Self-Regulatory Organizations; The Nasdaq Stock Market LLC; Notice of Filing and Immediate Effectiveness of Proposed Rule Change To Encourage Members To Contribute Liquidity to the Exchange by Offering Those That Maintain a Particular Minimum Trading Volume Lower Fees for Specified Market Data and Connectivity Products, 24070-24075 [2024-07227]
Download as PDF
24070
Federal Register / Vol. 89, No. 67 / Friday, April 5, 2024 / Notices
the most significant aspects of such
statements.
SECURITIES AND EXCHANGE
COMMISSION
[Release No. 34–99879; File No. SR–
NASDAQ–2024–016]
Self-Regulatory Organizations; The
Nasdaq Stock Market LLC; Notice of
Filing and Immediate Effectiveness of
Proposed Rule Change To Encourage
Members To Contribute Liquidity to the
Exchange by Offering Those That
Maintain a Particular Minimum Trading
Volume Lower Fees for Specified
Market Data and Connectivity Products
April 1, 2024.
Pursuant to Section 19(b)(1) of the
Securities Exchange Act of 1934 (the
‘‘Act’’),1 and Rule 19b–4 thereunder,2
notice is hereby given that on March 22,
2024, The Nasdaq Stock Market LLC
(‘‘Nasdaq’’ or ‘‘Exchange’’) filed with the
Securities and Exchange Commission
(‘‘SEC’’ or ‘‘Commission’’) the proposed
rule change as described in Items I, II
and III, below, which Items have been
prepared by the Exchange. The
Commission is publishing this notice to
solicit comments on the proposed rule
change from interested persons.
I. Self-Regulatory Organization’s
Statement of the Terms of Substance of
the Proposed Rule Change
The Exchange proposes to encourage
members to contribute liquidity to the
Exchange by offering those that
maintain a particular minimum trading
volume lower fees for specified market
data and connectivity products.
While these amendments are effective
upon filing, the Exchange has
designated the proposed amendments to
be operative on September 1, 2024.
The text of the proposed rule change
is available on the Exchange’s website at
https://listingcenter.nasdaq.com/
rulebook/nasdaq/rules, at the principal
office of the Exchange, and at the
Commission’s Public Reference Room.
khammond on DSKJM1Z7X2PROD with NOTICES
II. Self-Regulatory Organization’s
Statement of the Purpose of, and
Statutory Basis for, the Proposed Rule
Change
In its filing with the Commission, the
Exchange included statements
concerning the purpose of and basis for
the proposed rule change and discussed
any comments it received on the
proposed rule change. The text of these
statements may be examined at the
places specified in Item IV below. The
Exchange has prepared summaries, set
forth in sections A, B, and C below, of
1 15
2 17
U.S.C. 78s(b)(1).
CFR 240.19b–4.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:44 Apr 04, 2024
Jkt 262001
A. Self-Regulatory Organization’s
Statement of the Purpose of, and
Statutory Basis for, the Proposed Rule
Change
1. Purpose
The purpose of the proposed rule
change is to reward firms that meet a
minimum average daily displayed
volume with lower fees for Non-Display
Usage and the Exchange’s 40Gb and
10Gb Ultra high-speed connection to the
Exchange.3
Non-Display Usage
Non-Display Usage is any method of
accessing Nasdaq U.S. information that
involves access or use by a machine or
automated device without access or use
of a display by a natural person.
Examples of Non-Display Usage
include, but are not limited to:
• Automated trading;
• Automated order/quote generation
and/or order/quote pegging;
• Price referencing for use in
algorithmic trading;
• Price referencing for use in smart
order routing;
• Program trading and high frequency
trading;
• Order verification;
• Automated surveillance programs;
• Risk management;
• Automatic order cancellation, or
automatic error discovery;
• Clearing and settlement activities;
• Account maintenance (e.g.,
controlling margin for a customer
account); and
• ‘‘Hot’’ disaster recovery.
Although either top-of-book or depthof-book data can be used for NonDisplay Usage, the proposal modifies
fees for depth-of-book data only.4
Non-Display fees are currently
assessed on a per-subscriber 5 or perfirm basis. Monthly fees are $375 per
Subscriber for 1–39 subscribers; $15,000
per firm for 40–99 subscribers; $30,000
per firm for 100–249 subscribers; and
$75,000 per firm for 250 or more
subscribers.
Under the proposed rule change, a
member firm that meets the minimum
ADV threshold discussed below would
continue to pay those fees.
3 This proposal was initially filed on March 6,
2024, as SR–Nasdaq–2024–011. On March 20, 2024,
that filing was withdrawn and replaced with SR–
Nasdaq–2024–015. On March 22, 2024, SR–
Nasdaq–2024–015 was withdrawn and replaced
with the instant filing due to a technical error.
4 See Equity 7, Section 123 (Nasdaq Depth-ofBook data).
5 ‘‘Subscriber’’ is defined as a device or computer
terminal or an automated service which is entitled
to receive information.
PO 00000
Frm 00110
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
Firms that do not meet the minimum
ADV threshold, however, as well as
non-member firms, would pay the new
monthly fees of $500 per subscriber for
1–39 subscribers; $20,000 per firm for
40–99 subscribers; $40,000 per firm for
100–249 subscribers; and $100,000 per
firm for 250 or more subscribers.
Fiber Connections to the Exchange
(40Gb and 10Gb Ultra)
Nasdaq offers customers the
opportunity to co-locate their servers
and equipment within the Nasdaq Data
Center,6 allowing participants an
opportunity to reduce latency and
network complexity. Nasdaq offers a
variety of connectivity options to fit a
firm’s specific networking needs,
including the high-speed 40Gb and
10Gb Ultra networks.
All of Nasdaq’s colocation and
connectivity options offer customers
access to any or all Nasdaq exchanges
through a single connection.7 For
example, a firm that is a member of all
six Nasdaq exchanges that purchases
services in the Nasdaq Data Center such
as a 40G fiber connection, cabinet space,
cooling fans, and patch cables only
purchases these products or services
once to use them for all six Nasdaq
exchanges.
Nasdaq currently charges members an
ongoing monthly fee of $21,100 for the
40Gb fiber connection and $15,825 for
the 10Gb Ultra connection to the Nasdaq
exchanges. Under the proposed rule
change, a firm that meets the minimum
ADV threshold would continue to pay
those fees.
Member firms that do not meet the
minimum ADV threshold discussed
below, as well as non-member firms,
would pay the new monthly fee of
$23,700 for the 40Gb fiber connection
and $17,800 for the 10Gb Ultra
connection.
Minimum ADV
The proposal introduces the new term
‘‘Minimum ADV,’’ which will mean the
introduction by a member of at least one
million shares of added executed
displayed liquidity on average per
trading day in all securities through one
or more of the member’s market
participant identifiers (‘‘MPIDs’’) on the
Nasdaq Market Center. Average daily
volume is calculated as the total volume
of shares executed for all added
6 See Nasdaq Co-Location (CoLo) Services,
available at https://www.nasdaqtrader.com/trader.
aspx?id=colo; Stock Exchange Data Center &
Trading, available at https://www.nasdaq.com/
solutions/nasdaq-co-location.
7 See Securities Exchange Act Release No. 84571
(November 9, 2018), 83 FR 57758 (November 16,
2018) (SR–Nasdaq–2018–086).
E:\FR\FM\05APN1.SGM
05APN1
Federal Register / Vol. 89, No. 67 / Friday, April 5, 2024 / Notices
khammond on DSKJM1Z7X2PROD with NOTICES
displayed orders in all securities during
the trading month divided by the
number of trading days in that month,
averaged over the six-month period
preceding the billing month, or the date
the firm became a member, whichever is
shorter. New members will be deemed
to meet the Minimum ADV for the first
month of operation. Minimum ADV
excludes sponsored access by a member
on behalf of a third party. The minimum
ADV threshold was designed to be
accessible to all members to promote
wide engagement with the Exchange.
Nasdaq does not expect any member
to be disadvantaged by the proposal.
Nasdaq is a maker-taker platform and, as
such, offers rebates to members that
offer displayed liquidity. With these
rebates, no member should have any
difficulty posting and executing
sufficient displayed liquidity to meet
the ADV threshold. The threshold is,
moreover, set at a level that Nasdaq
believes any member—even smaller
members—should be able to meet
without significant effort. Because the
threshold applies to displayed liquidity
only, the proposal should not impact
the Best Execution obligations of any
member. If all members were to meet
this threshold, the proposal would add
an incremental 60–80 million shares to
Nasdaq’s accessible liquidity.
Non-members that, by definition, do
not post displayed liquidity to the
market would pay the higher fees. This
is because the non-members do not
directly contribute order flow to the
Exchange, but nevertheless benefit from
that order flow through tighter spreads,
better prices, and the other advantages
of a more liquid platform, as discussed
in further detail under Statutory Basis.
The Proposal Will Promote Competition
Among Trading Venues
Exchanges, like all trading venues,
compete as platforms. All elements of
the platform—trade executions, market
data, connectivity, membership, and
listings—operate in concert. Trade
executions increase the value of market
data; market data functions as an
advertisement for on-exchange trading;
listings increase the value of trade
executions and market data; and greater
liquidity on the exchange enhances the
value of ports and colocation services.
As discussed under Statutory Basis,
we have attached a data-based analysis
demonstrating how platform
competition works entitled ‘‘How
Exchanges Compete: An Economic
Analysis of Platform Competition’’ as
Exhibit 3. The paper explains that
exchanges are multi-sided platforms,
whose value is dependent on attracting
users to multiple sides of the platform.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:44 Apr 04, 2024
Jkt 262001
Issuers need investors, and every trade
requires two sides to trade. To make its
platform attractive to multiple
constituencies, an exchange must
consider inter-side externalities,
meaning demand for one set of platform
services depends on the demand for
other services. This proposal is designed
to promote competition by providing an
incentive for members to provide
liquidity (therefore attracting investors
and increasing the overall value of the
platform) through charging lower fees
for other platform services (i.e., market
data and connectivity). This will lead to
more displayed liquidity on the
Exchange, enhancing and enriching the
market data distributed to the industry,
which then increases the amount of
interest in the platform. This will also
enable the Exchange to offer investors a
more robust, lower cost-trading
experience through tighter spreads and
more efficient trading as discussed in
Exhibit 3, placing it in a better
competitive position relative to other
exchanges and trading venues.8
2. Statutory Basis
The Exchange believes that its
proposal is consistent with Section 6(b)
of the Act,9 in general, and furthers the
objectives of Sections 6(b)(4) and 6(b)(5)
of the Act,10 in particular, in that it
provides for the equitable allocation of
reasonable dues, fees, and other charges
among members and issuers and other
persons using any facility, and is not
designed to permit unfair
discrimination between customers,
issuers, brokers, or dealers.
Fees Produced in a Competitive
Environment Are an Equitable
Allocation of Reasonable Dues, Fees,
and Other Charges
Reliance on competitive solutions is
fundamental to the Act. Where
significant competitive forces constrain
fees, fee levels meet the Act’s standard
for the ‘‘equitable allocation of
reasonable dues, fees, and other charges
among members and issuers and other
persons using its facilities,’’ 11 unless
there is a substantial countervailing
basis to find that a fee does not meet
some other requirement of the Act.12
8 To the degree that the additional liquidity is
moved from off-exchange venues to on-exchange
platforms, overall market transparency will improve
as well.
9 15 U.S.C. 78f(b).
10 15 U.S.C. 78f(b)(4) and (5).
11 See 15 U.S.C. 78f(b)(4).
12 See U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission,
‘‘Staff Guidance on SRO Rule filings Relating to
Fees’’ (May 21, 2019), available at https://
www.sec.gov/tm/staff-guidance-sro-rule-filings-fees
(‘‘Fee Guidance’’) (‘‘If significant competitive forces
constrain the fee at issue, fee levels will be
PO 00000
Frm 00111
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
24071
Evidence of platform competition
demonstrates that each exchange
product is sold in a competitive
environment, and its fees will be an
equitable allocation of reasonable dues,
fees, and other charges, provided that
nothing about the product or its fee
structure impairs competition.13
Congress directed the Commission to
‘‘rely on ‘competition, whenever
possible, in meeting its regulatory
responsibilities for overseeing the SROs
and the national market system.’ ’’ 14
Following this mandate, the
Commission and the courts have
repeatedly expressed their preference
for competition over regulatory
intervention to determine prices,
products, and services in the securities
markets.
In Regulation NMS, the Commission
highlighted the importance of market
forces in determining prices and SRO
revenues and recognized that regulation
of the national market system ‘‘has been
remarkably successful in promoting
market competition in its broader forms
that are most important to investors and
listed companies.’’ 15
As a result, the Commission has long
relied on competitive forces to
determine whether a fee proposal is
equitable, fair, reasonable, and not
unreasonably or unfairly discriminatory.
In 2008, the Commission explained that
‘‘[i]f competitive forces are operative,
the self-interest of the exchanges
themselves will work powerfully to
constrain unreasonable or unfair
behavior.’’ 16 In 2019, Commission Staff
reaffirmed that ‘‘[i]f significant
competitive forces constrain the fee at
issue, fee levels will be presumed to be
fair and reasonable . . . .’’ 17
Accordingly, ‘‘the existence of
significant competition provides a
substantial basis for finding that the
terms of an exchange’s fee proposal are
equitable, fair, reasonable, and not
presumed to be fair and reasonable, and the inquiry
is whether there is a substantial countervailing
basis to find that the fee terms nevertheless fail to
meet an applicable requirement of the Exchange Act
(e.g., that fees are equitably allocated, not unfairly
discriminatory, and not an undue burden on
competition).’’).
13 Nothing in the Act requires proof of productby-product competition.
14 NetCoalition v. SEC, 715 F.3d 342, 534–35
(D.C. Cir. 2013); see also H.R. Rep. No. 94–229 at
92 (1975) (‘‘[I]t is the intent of the conferees that
the national market system evolve through the
interplay of competitive forces as unnecessary
regulatory restrictions are removed.’’).
15 See Securities Exchange Act Release No. 51808
(June 9, 2005), 70 FR 37496, 37499 (June 29, 2005)
(‘‘Regulation NMS Adopting Release’’).
16 See Securities Exchange Act Release No. 59039
(December 2, 2008), 73 FR 74770 (December 9,
2008) (SR–NYSEArca–2006–21).
17 See Fee Guidance, supra n.10.
E:\FR\FM\05APN1.SGM
05APN1
24072
Federal Register / Vol. 89, No. 67 / Friday, April 5, 2024 / Notices
unreasonably or unfairly
discriminatory.’’ 18 Consistent with the
Commission’s longstanding focus on
competition, Commission Staff have
indicated that they would only look at
factors outside of the competitive
market if a ‘‘proposal lacks persuasive
evidence that the proposed fee is
constrained by significant competitive
forces.’’ 19
Nothing in the Act Requires an
Examination of Fees in Isolation
The Act mandates the ‘‘equitable
allocation of reasonable dues, fees, and
other charges among members and
issuers and other persons using its
facilities.’’ 20 This provision refers
generally to ‘‘reasonable dues, fees, and
other charges’’ as a whole, not
individual fees. Nothing in the Act
requires the individual examination of
18 See
id.
id. In the Fee Guidance, the Staff indicated
that ‘‘[w]hen reviewing rule filing proposals . . .
[it] is mindful of recent opinions by the D.C.
Circuit,’’ including Susquehanna International
Group, LLP v. SEC, 866 F.3d 442 (D.C. Cir. 2017).
However, the D.C. Circuit’s decision in
Susquehanna is irrelevant to the Commission’s
review of immediately effective SRO fee filings.
Susquehanna involved the Commission’s approval
of a rule proposed under Section 19(b)(2) of the Act,
not its evaluation of whether to temporarily
suspend an SRO’s immediately effective fee filing
under Section 19(b)(3). A comparison of Sections
19(b)(2) and 19(b)(3) of the Act makes clear that the
Commission is not required to undertake the same
independent review, and make the same findings
and determinations, for Section 19(b)(3) filings that
it must for Section 19(b)(2) filings. In particular,
Section 19(b)(2) requires the Commission to ‘‘find[ ]
that [a] proposed rule change is consistent with
the’’ Act before approving the rule. 15 U.S.C.
78s(b)(2)(C)(i). Section 19(b)(3), by contrast, imbues
the Commission with discretion, stating that it
‘‘may temporarily suspend’’ an immediately
effective rule filing where ‘‘it appears to the
Commission that such action is necessary or
appropriate.’’ As the Supreme Court has explained,
statutes stating that an agency ‘‘may’’—but need
not—take certain action are ‘‘written in the
language of permission and discretion.’’ S. Ry. Co.
v. Seaboard Allied Milling, 442 U.S. 444, 455
(1979); see also Crooker v. SEC, 161 F.2d 944, 949
(1st Cir. 1947) (per curiam). The ‘‘contrast’’ between
Sections 19(b)(2) and 19(b)(3), the Commission
itself has explained, ‘‘reflects the fundamental
difference in the way Congress intended for
different types of rules to be treated.’’ Brief of
Respondent SEC, NetCoalition v. SEC, 715 F.3d 342
(D.C. Cir. 2013) (Nos. 10–1421 et al.); see also id.
at 42–43 (‘‘[W]hile the Commission’s authority to
suspend a fee under Subsection (3)(C) is permissive,
its duties under Subsection (2) are stated in
mandatory terms.’’). Thus, neither Susquehanna,
nor Section 19(b)(3) of the Act, requires the
Commission to make independent findings that an
immediately effective SRO fee filing such as this
one is consistent with the Act. To the degree that
the Susquehanna decision is applicable to any
Commission action, however, the court held that
the Commission is required to ‘‘itself find or
determine’’ that a proposal meets statutory
requirements, explaining that the Commission is
‘‘obligated to make an independent review’’ of an
SRO’s proposal, and not rely solely on the work of
the SRO. See 866 F.3d at 446.
20 See 15 U.S.C. 78f(b)(4).
khammond on DSKJM1Z7X2PROD with NOTICES
19 See
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:44 Apr 04, 2024
Jkt 262001
specific product fees in isolation.
Provided that a proposed rule change
does not in and of itself undermine
competition, evidence of platform
competition is sufficient to show that
the product operates in a competitive
environment.
A determination of whether a
proposal permits unfair discrimination
between customers, issuers, brokers, or
dealers remains a separate productspecific inquiry.
The Commission Has Recognized That
Exchanges Are Subject to Significant
Competitive Forces in the Market for
Order Flow
The fact that the market for order flow
is competitive has long been recognized
by the courts. In NetCoalition v.
Securities and Exchange Commission,
the D.C. Circuit stated, ‘‘[n]o one
disputes that competition for order flow
is ‘fierce.’ . . . As the SEC explained,
‘[i]n the U.S. national market system,
buyers and sellers of securities, and the
broker-dealers that act as their orderrouting agents, have a wide range of
choices of where to route orders for
execution’; [and] ‘no exchange can
afford to take its market share
percentages for granted’ because ‘no
exchange possesses a monopoly,
regulatory or otherwise, in the execution
of order flow from broker dealers.’ ’’ 21
All Exchange Products Are Subject to
Competition—Not Just Those Directly
Related to Order Flow
As discussed more fully in our
analysis, ‘‘How Exchanges Compete: An
Economic Analysis of Platform
Competition’’ (Exhibit 3), competition is
not limited to order flow. Data shows
that the combination of explicit all-in
costs to trade and other implicit costs
has largely equalized the cost to trade
across venues.22 This is a function of the
21 See NetCoalition, 615 F.3d at 539 (D.C. Cir.
2010) (quoting Securities Exchange Act Release No.
59039 (December 2, 2008), 73 FR 74770, 74782–83
(December 9, 2008) (SR–NYSEArca–2006–21)).
22 Competition across platforms constrains
platform fees and results in ‘‘all-in’’ costs becoming
equal across platforms. The Staff Guidance on SRO
Rule Filings Relating to Fees, however, states that
platform competition requires that the ‘‘overall
return of the platform, rather than the return of any
particular fees charged to a type of customer, . . .
be used to assess the competitiveness of the
platform’s market,’’ and that ‘‘[a]n SRO that wishes
to rely on total platform theory must provide
evidence demonstrating that competitive forces are
sufficient to constrain the SRO’s aggregate return
across the platform.’’ See Fee Guidance, supra n.10
(emphasis added). We do not know, and cannot
determine, whether returns (as opposed to fees) are
equalized across platforms, because we do not have
detailed cost information from other exchanges. An
analysis of returns, however, is unnecessary to
show that competition constrains fees given that, as
we demonstrate below, platform competition can be
demonstrated solely by examining costs to users.
PO 00000
Frm 00112
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
fact that, if the all-in cost to the user of
interacting with an exchange exceeds
market price, customers can and do shift
their purchases and trading activity to
other exchanges, and therefore the
exchange must adjust one or more of its
fees to attract customers.
This conclusion is particularly
striking given that different exchanges
engage in a variety of business models
and offer an array of pricing options to
appeal to different customer types. The
largest exchanges operate maker-taker
platforms, offering rebates to attract
trading liquidity, which allows them to
maintain actionable quotes with high
liquidity and offer high-quality market
data. The negative price charged to
liquidity providers through rebates is
part of the platform because it serves to
create features attractive to other
participants, including oftentimes tight
spreads, actionable and lit quotes, and
more valuable market data.
Inverted venues, in contrast, have the
opposite price structure—liquidity
providers pay to add liquidity, while
liquidity takers earn a rebate. These
platforms offer less liquidity, but better
queue priority, faster fills, and lower
effective spreads for investors. There are
a wide range of other pricing models
and product offerings among the dozens
of lit and unlit trading venues that
compete in the marketplace in addition
to these examples.
The different strategies among
exchanges also manifest in the pricing
of other services, such as market data
and connectivity. Some exchanges
charge for such services, while others
charge little or nothing (typically
because the exchange is new or has little
liquidity), just as some exchanges
charge a fee per trade, while others pay
rebates.
In assessing competition for exchange
services, we must consider not only
explicit costs, such as fees for trading,
market data, and connectivity, but also
the implicit costs of trading on an
exchange. The realized spread, or
markout, captures the implicit cost to
trade on a platform.
The concept of markout was created
by market makers trying to capture the
spread while providing a two-sided (bid
and offer) market. For market makers,
being filled on the bid or the offer can
cause a loss if the fill changes market
prices. For example, a fill on a market
maker’s bid just as the stock price falls
results in a ‘‘virtual loss,’’ because the
market maker has a long position with
a new bid lower than the fill.
Negative markouts can be beneficial.
For example, if an institutional investor
is working a large buy order, negative
markouts represent fills as the market
E:\FR\FM\05APN1.SGM
05APN1
Federal Register / Vol. 89, No. 67 / Friday, April 5, 2024 / Notices
falls, allowing later orders to be placed
sooner, and likely at a better price,
reducing the opportunity costs as well
as explicit cost of building the position.
Data suggests that market participants
employ sophisticated analytic tools to
weigh the cost of immediate liquidity
and lower opportunity costs against
better spread capture (lower markouts)
and explicit trading costs. As discussed
in greater detail in Exhibit 3, the venues
with the highest explicit costs—
typically inverted and fee-fee venues—
have the lowest implicit costs from
markouts and vice versa. Higher
positive markouts mean more spread
capture, but those venues also tend to
have the highest explicit costs, and
provide the least liquidity, and positive
externalities, to the market.
Considering both the explicit costs
charged by exchanges for their various
joint products and the implicit costs
incurred by traders to trade on various
exchanges, the data show that all-in
trading costs across exchanges are
largely equalized, regardless of different
trading strategies offered by each
platform for each individual service.
As such, platform competition has
resulted in a competitive environment
in the market for exchange services, in
which trading platforms are constrained
by other platforms’ offerings, taking into
consideration the all-in cost of
interacting with the platform. This
constraint is a natural consequence of
competition and demonstrates that no
exchange platform can charge excessive
fees and expect to remain competitive,
thereby constraining fees on all
products sold as part of the platform.
The existence of platform-level
competition also explains why some
consumers route orders to the exchange
with the highest explicit trading costs
even though other exchanges offer free
or a net rebate for trading.23
khammond on DSKJM1Z7X2PROD with NOTICES
Exchanges Compete at Both the Platform
and Product Level
Exchange customers are differentiated
in the value they place on the different
products offered by exchanges and in
their willingness to pay for those
products. This occurs both on a firmwide and a transaction basis; for
example, individual customers ‘‘multihome’’ on various platforms, and are
thus able to route different trades to
different platforms to take advantage of
favorable economics offered on a tradeto-trade basis.
23 Empirical evidence also shows that market data
is more valuable from exchanges with more
liquidity. Many customers decide not to take data
from smaller markets, even though they are free or
much lower cost than larger markets.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:44 Apr 04, 2024
Jkt 262001
Exchanges compete by offering
differentiated packages of pricing and
products to attract different categories of
customer. As in any competitive market,
consumers will ‘‘vote with their feet,’’
incentivizing platforms to supply an
array of pricing and product offerings
that suit diverse consumer needs far
more effectively than a uniform, onesize-fits-some rigid product offering. If
an exchange’s pricing for a particular
product gets out of line, such that its
total return is boosted above
competitive levels, market forces will
discipline that approach because
competing exchanges will quickly
attract customer volume through more
attractive all-in trading costs.
In addition, if a particular package of
pricing and products is not attractive to
a sufficient volume of customers in a
particular category, those customers
may elect not to purchase the service.
This is why exchanges compete at a
product level, as well as based on allin trading costs.
Exchanges Compete With Off-Exchange
Trading Platforms in Addition to Other
Exchanges
As the SEC recently noted in its
market infrastructure proposal,24 the
number of transactions completed on
non-exchange venues has been growing.
Allowing exchanges to compete as
platforms will help exchanges compete
against non-exchange venues, and, to
the degree order flow is shifted from
non-exchange to exchange venues,
overall market transparency will
improve.25
Exchanges have a unique role to play
in market transparency because they
publish an array of pre- and post-trade
data that non-exchange venues, almost
entirely, do not. Greater transparency
benefits non-exchange venues by
enabling them to provide more accurate
pricing to their customers, and by
helping such venues set their own
prices, benchmark, analyze the total cost
of ownership, and assess their own
trading strategies.
Allowing exchanges to compete
effectively as platforms has other
positive network effects. Larger trading
platforms offer lower average trading
costs. As trading platforms attract more
liquidity, bid-ask spreads tighten, search
24 See Regulation NMS: Minimum Pricing
Increments, Access Fees, and Transparency of
Better Price Orders, Securities Exchange Act
Release No. 96494 (File No. S7–30–22), available at
https://www.sec.gov/rules/proposed/2022/3496494.pdf.
25 Non-exchange venues rely on market data
distributed by exchanges to set prices. Greater
transparency allows both exchange and nonexchange venues to operate more effectively and
efficiently.
PO 00000
Frm 00113
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
24073
costs fall (by limiting the number of
venues that a customer needs to check
to assess the market), and connection
costs decrease, as customers have no
need to connect to all venues.26 The
whole is therefore greater (in the sense
that it is more efficient) than the sum of
the parts.
This is not to say that smaller
established trading platforms do not
have a role to play. They provide
specialized services that cater to
individual customer needs. These
specialized services help the smaller
exchanges grow by driving liquidity to
their platforms, and, if they are
successful, achieve the economies of
scale that benefit the larger enterprises.
Because the total costs of interacting
with an exchange are roughly equal,
smaller exchanges offset higher trading
costs with lower connectivity, market
data, or other fees. While the mix of fees
will change as exchanges grow, the allin cost of interacting with the exchange
remains roughly the same.
Acknowledging that exchanges
compete as platforms and approving
fees expeditiously on that basis will
improve the ability of exchanges to
compete against non-exchange venues,
and, to the degree order flow is shifted
to exchanges, both transparency and
efficiency will improve.
The Proposed Fees Are Equitable and
Reasonable Because They Will Be
Subject to Competition
This proposal offers member firms an
incentive to display liquidity through
lower non-display and connectivity
fees. The intent is to generate a
‘‘virtuous cycle,’’ in which the proposed
fee structure will attract more liquidity
to the Exchange, making it a more
attractive trading venue, and thereby
attracting more liquidity.
Incentive programs have been widely
adopted by exchanges, and are
reasonable, equitable, and nondiscriminatory because they are open on
an equal basis to similarly situated
members and provide additional
benefits or discounts that are reasonably
related to the value to an exchange’s
market quality and activity.27
26 In addition, Nasdaq’s experience shows that
fewer customers connect with smaller trading
venues than with larger venues.
27 See, e.g., Securities Exchange Act Release No.
92493 (July 26, 2021), 86 FR 41129 (July 30, 2021)
(SR–CboeEDGX–2021–034) (proposal to provide
discount to new members that meet certain volume
thresholds, noting that ‘‘relative volume-based
incentives and discounts have been widely adopted
by exchanges . . . and are reasonable, equitable and
non-discriminatory because they are open on an
equal basis to similarly situated members and
provide additional benefits or discounts that are
E:\FR\FM\05APN1.SGM
Continued
05APN1
24074
Federal Register / Vol. 89, No. 67 / Friday, April 5, 2024 / Notices
khammond on DSKJM1Z7X2PROD with NOTICES
The proposal will contribute to
market quality because it will help bring
new order flow to the Exchange. Greater
displayed liquidity on the Exchange
offers investors deeper, more liquid
markets and execution opportunities.
Increased order flow benefits
investors by deepening the Exchange’s
liquidity pool, potentially providing
greater execution incentives and
opportunities, offering additional
flexibility for all investors to enjoy cost
savings, supporting the quality of price
discovery, promoting market
transparency, and lowering spreads
between bids and offers and thereby
lowering investor costs. To the degree
that liquidity is attracted from dark
venues, that liquidity also increases
transparency for the market overall,
providing investors with more
information about market trends.
The proposal will help members that
meet the minimum ADV threshold
maintain lower costs and will benefit
them through the many positive
externalities associated with a more
liquid exchange.
The competition among exchanges as
trading platforms, as well as the
competition between exchanges and
alternative trading venues, constrain
exchanges from charging excessive fees
for any exchange products, including
trading, listings, ports, and market data.
Indeed, the fees that arise from the
competition among trading platforms
may be too low because they fail to
reflect the benefits to the market as a
whole of exchange products and
services, allowing other venues to freeride on these investments by the
exchange platforms, increasing
fragmentation and search costs.
As long as total returns are
constrained by competitive forces—as
demonstrated in detail by the report
provided as Exhibit 3—there is no
regulatory basis to be concerned with
pricing of particular elements offered on
a platform. Indeed, regulatory
constraints in this environment are
likely to reduce consumer welfare by
constraining certain exchanges from
offering packages of pricing and
reasonably related to (i) the value to an exchange’s
market quality and (ii) associated higher levels of
market activity . . . .’’) (not suspended by
Commission); see also Securities Exchange Act
Release No. 53790 (May 11, 2006), 71 FR 28738
(May 17, 2006) (SR–Phlx–2006–04) (‘‘The
Commission recognizes that volume-based
discounts of fees are not uncommon, and where the
discount can be applied objectively, it is consistent
with Rule 603. For the same reasons noted above,
the Commission believes that the fee structure
meets the standard in section 6(b)(4) of the Act in
that the proposed rule change provides for the
equitable allocation of reasonable dues, fees, and
other charges among the Exchange’s members and
issuers and other persons using its facilities.’’).
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:44 Apr 04, 2024
Jkt 262001
products that would be attractive to
certain sets of consumers, thus
impeding competition with venues that
are not subject to the same regulatory
limitations and reducing the benefits of
competition to customers.
The Proposal Is Not Unfairly
Discriminatory
The proposal is not unfairly
discriminatory. Non-Display Usage and
the Exchange’s 40Gb and 10Gb Ultra
high-speed connections will be offered
to all members and non-members on
like terms. It is also not unfair to charge
more to firms that do not directly
contribute order flow to the Exchange,
but nevertheless benefit from that order
flow through tighter spreads, better
prices, and the other advantages of a
more liquid platform.
Specifically, the proposal is not
unfairly discriminatory with respect to
either members or non-members.
With respect to members, all members
that meet the ADV threshold will be
charged lower fees. With respect to
smaller members, Nasdaq offers rebates
to members that offer displayed
liquidity. With these rebates, any
member—even smaller members—
should have the ability to post sufficient
displayed liquidity to meet the ADV
threshold.
The proposal is not unfairly
discriminatory with respect to nonmembers broker-dealers, which include
brokers routing trades through members
and off-exchange trading platforms that
use exchange data to execute trades,
because they have the option of
becoming members to obtain lower fees
under the proposal, and because they
realize the benefits of higher liquidity—
including tighter spreads and better
prices—and it is not unfair
discrimination to charge a higher fee for
that benefit.
The proposal is not unfairly
discriminatory with respect to nonmember firms that are not brokerdealers, such as market data vendors
and index providers, because they also
benefit from the value that the
additional liquidity generated by this
proposal will provide to the trading
platform. As noted above, incentivizing
higher levels of liquidity enhances and
enriches the market data distributed to
the industry, and increases the overall
value of platform. It is not unfair for
such parties to pay a higher fee to reflect
the greater value of the platform.
Discounts for specific categories of
market participants are well-established;
examples include non-professional fees,
PO 00000
Frm 00114
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
broker-dealer enterprise licenses, and a
media enterprise license.28
For all of the foregoing reasons, the
Exchange believes that the proposal is
consistent with the Act.
B. Self-Regulatory Organization’s
Statement on Burden on Competition
In accordance with Section 6(b)(8) of
the Act,29 the Exchange believes that the
proposed rule change will not impose
any burden on competition that is not
necessary or appropriate in furtherance
of the purposes of the Act.
Rather, as discussed above, the
Exchange believes that the proposed
changes would increase competition by
attracting additional liquidity to the
Exchange, which the Exchange believes
will enhance market quality, thereby
promoting market depth, price
discovery, and transparency and
enhancing order execution
opportunities for member organizations.
As a result, the Exchange believes that
the proposed change furthers the
Commission’s goal in adopting
Regulation NMS of fostering integrated
competition among orders, which
promotes ‘‘more efficient pricing of
individual stocks for all types of orders,
large and small.’’ 30
Intra-market Competition. Nothing in
the proposal burdens intra-market
competition (the competition among
consumers of exchange data) because
the proposed fee structure would be
available to all similarly situated market
participants, and, as such, the proposed
change would not impose a disparate
burden on different market participants.
Intermarket Competition. Nothing in
the proposal burdens intermarket
competition (the competition among
self-regulatory organizations) because
competitors are free to modify their own
fees in response.
As previously discussed, the
Exchange operates in a highly
competitive market. Members have
numerous alternative venues that they
may participate on and direct their
order flow to, including other equities
exchanges, off-exchange venues, and
alternative trading systems. Participants
can readily choose to send their orders
to other exchange and off-exchange
venues if they deem fee levels at those
28 See, e.g., The Nasdaq Stock Market, Price List—
U.S. Equities, available at https://
www.nasdaqtrader.com/Trader.aspx?id=DPUSData
(providing discounts for Non-Professional
subscribers for Nasdaq TotalView and other market
data products, enterprise licenses for broker-dealers
for multiple market data products, and a digital
media enterprise license for Nasdaq Basic).
29 15 U.S.C. 78f(b)(8).
30 Securities Exchange Act Release No. 51808, 70
FR 37496, 37498–99 (June 29, 2005) (Regulation
NMS).
E:\FR\FM\05APN1.SGM
05APN1
Federal Register / Vol. 89, No. 67 / Friday, April 5, 2024 / Notices
other venues to be more favorable. In
such an environment, the Exchange
must continually adjust its fees and
rebates to remain competitive with other
exchanges and with off-exchange
venues.
C. Self-Regulatory Organization’s
Statement on Comments on the
Proposed Rule Change Received From
Members, Participants, or Others
No written comments were either
solicited or received.
III. Date of Effectiveness of the
Proposed Rule Change and Timing for
Commission Action
The foregoing rule change has become
effective pursuant to Section
19(b)(3)(A)(ii) of the Act.31
At any time within 60 days of the
filing of the proposed rule change, the
Commission summarily may
temporarily suspend such rule change if
it appears to the Commission that such
action is: (i) necessary or appropriate in
the public interest; (ii) for the protection
of investors; or (iii) otherwise in
furtherance of the purposes of the Act.
If the Commission takes such action, the
Commission shall institute proceedings
to determine whether the proposed rule
should be approved or disapproved.
IV. Solicitation of Comments
Interested persons are invited to
submit written data, views and
arguments concerning the foregoing,
including whether the proposed rule
change is consistent with the Act.
Comments may be submitted by any of
the following methods:
khammond on DSKJM1Z7X2PROD with NOTICES
Electronic Comments
• Use the Commission’s internet
comment form (https://www.sec.gov/
rules/sro.shtml); or
• Send an email to rule-comments@
sec.gov. Please include file number SR–
NASDAQ–2024–016 on the subject line.
Paper Comments
• Send paper comments in triplicate
to Secretary, Securities and Exchange
Commission, 100 F Street NE,
Washington, DC 20549–1090.
All submissions should refer to file
number SR–NASDAQ–2024–016. This
file number should be included on the
subject line if email is used. To help the
Commission process and review your
comments more efficiently, please use
only one method. The Commission will
post all comments on the Commission’s
internet website (https://www.sec.gov/
rules/sro.shtml). Copies of the
submission, all subsequent
amendments, all written statements
with respect to the proposed rule
change that are filed with the
Commission, and all written
communications relating to the
proposed rule change between the
Commission and any person, other than
those that may be withheld from the
public in accordance with the
provisions of 5 U.S.C. 552, will be
available for website viewing and
printing in the Commission’s Public
Reference Room, 100 F Street NE,
Washington, DC 20549, on official
business days between the hours of 10
a.m. and 3 p.m. Copies of the filing also
will be available for inspection and
copying at the principal office of the
Exchange. Do not include personal
identifiable information in submissions;
you should submit only information
that you wish to make available
publicly. We may redact in part or
withhold entirely from publication
submitted material that is obscene or
subject to copyright protection. All
submissions should refer to file number
SR–NASDAQ–2024–016 and should be
submitted on or before April 26, 2024.
For the Commission, by the Division of
Trading and Markets, pursuant to delegated
authority.32
J. Matthew DeLesDernier,
Deputy Secretary.
[FR Doc. 2024–07227 Filed 4–4–24; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 8011–01–P
SECURITIES AND EXCHANGE
COMMISSION
[Release No. 34–99881; File No. SR–
NYSEARCA–2024–30]
Self-Regulatory Organizations; NYSE
Arca, Inc.; Notice of Filing and
Immediate Effectiveness of Proposed
Rule Change To Amend Rule 7.4–E
April 1, 2024.
Pursuant to Section 19(b)(1) of the
Securities Exchange Act of 1934 (the
‘‘Act’’),1 and Rule 19b–4 thereunder,2
notice is hereby given that on March 25,
2024, NYSE Arca, Inc. (‘‘NYSE Arca’’ or
the ‘‘Exchange’’) filed with the
Securities and Exchange Commission
(the ‘‘Commission’’) the proposed rule
change as described in Items I and II
below, which Items have been prepared
by the self-regulatory organization. The
Commission is publishing this notice to
solicit comments on the proposed rule
change from interested persons.
32 17
CFR 200.30–3(a)(12).
U.S.C. 78s(b)(1).
2 17 CFR 240.19b–4.
1 15
31 15
U.S.C. 78s(b)(3)(A)(ii).
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:44 Apr 04, 2024
Jkt 262001
PO 00000
Frm 00115
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
24075
I. Self-Regulatory Organization’s
Statement of the Terms of Substance of
the Proposed Rule Change
The Exchange proposes to amend
Rule 7.4–E (Ex-Dividend or Ex-Right
Dates) to conform to amendments to
Rule 15c6–1(a) of the Act to shorten the
standard settlement cycle for most
broker-dealer transactions from two
business days after the trade date
(‘‘T+2’’) to one business day after the
trade date (‘‘T+1’’). The proposed rule
change is available on the Exchange’s
website at www.nyse.com, at the
principal office of the Exchange, and at
the Commission’s Public Reference
Room.
II. Self-Regulatory Organization’s
Statement of the Purpose of, and
Statutory Basis for, the Proposed Rule
Change
In its filing with the Commission, the
self-regulatory organization included
statements concerning the purpose of,
and basis for, the proposed rule change
and discussed any comments it received
on the proposed rule change. The text
of those statements may be examined at
the places specified in Item IV below.
The Exchange has prepared summaries,
set forth in sections A, B, and C below,
of the most significant parts of such
statements.
A. Self-Regulatory Organization’s
Statement of the Purpose of, and the
Statutory Basis for, the Proposed Rule
Change
1. Purpose
On March 6, 2023, the Commission
adopted amendments to Rule 15c6–1(a)
of the Act to shorten the standard
settlement cycle for most broker-dealer
transactions from T+2 to T+1.3
Accordingly, the Exchange proposes to
amend Rule 7.4–E to conform with the
amendments to Rule 15c6–1(a) and
reflect a standard settlement cycle of
T+1.
Rule 7.4–E currently provides that
transactions in stocks traded ‘‘regular
way’’ are generally ‘‘ex-dividend’’ or
‘‘ex-rights’’ on the business day
preceding the record date fixed by the
company or the date of the closing of
transfer books. The rule further provides
that, if the record date or closing of
transfer books occur on a day other than
a business day, transactions would be
‘‘ex-dividend’’ or ‘‘ex-rights’’ on the
second preceding business day.
The Exchange proposes to amend
Rule 7.4–E to provide, in conformity
3 See Securities Exchange Act Release No. 96930,
88 FR 13872 (March 6, 2023) (‘‘T+1 Adopting
Release’’).
E:\FR\FM\05APN1.SGM
05APN1
Agencies
[Federal Register Volume 89, Number 67 (Friday, April 5, 2024)]
[Notices]
[Pages 24070-24075]
From the Federal Register Online via the Government Publishing Office [www.gpo.gov]
[FR Doc No: 2024-07227]
[[Page 24070]]
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
SECURITIES AND EXCHANGE COMMISSION
[Release No. 34-99879; File No. SR-NASDAQ-2024-016]
Self-Regulatory Organizations; The Nasdaq Stock Market LLC;
Notice of Filing and Immediate Effectiveness of Proposed Rule Change To
Encourage Members To Contribute Liquidity to the Exchange by Offering
Those That Maintain a Particular Minimum Trading Volume Lower Fees for
Specified Market Data and Connectivity Products
April 1, 2024.
Pursuant to Section 19(b)(1) of the Securities Exchange Act of 1934
(the ``Act''),\1\ and Rule 19b-4 thereunder,\2\ notice is hereby given
that on March 22, 2024, The Nasdaq Stock Market LLC (``Nasdaq'' or
``Exchange'') filed with the Securities and Exchange Commission
(``SEC'' or ``Commission'') the proposed rule change as described in
Items I, II and III, below, which Items have been prepared by the
Exchange. The Commission is publishing this notice to solicit comments
on the proposed rule change from interested persons.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1\ 15 U.S.C. 78s(b)(1).
\2\ 17 CFR 240.19b-4.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
I. Self-Regulatory Organization's Statement of the Terms of Substance
of the Proposed Rule Change
The Exchange proposes to encourage members to contribute liquidity
to the Exchange by offering those that maintain a particular minimum
trading volume lower fees for specified market data and connectivity
products.
While these amendments are effective upon filing, the Exchange has
designated the proposed amendments to be operative on September 1,
2024.
The text of the proposed rule change is available on the Exchange's
website at https://listingcenter.nasdaq.com/rulebook/nasdaq/rules, at
the principal office of the Exchange, and at the Commission's Public
Reference Room.
II. Self-Regulatory Organization's Statement of the Purpose of, and
Statutory Basis for, the Proposed Rule Change
In its filing with the Commission, the Exchange included statements
concerning the purpose of and basis for the proposed rule change and
discussed any comments it received on the proposed rule change. The
text of these statements may be examined at the places specified in
Item IV below. The Exchange has prepared summaries, set forth in
sections A, B, and C below, of the most significant aspects of such
statements.
A. Self-Regulatory Organization's Statement of the Purpose of, and
Statutory Basis for, the Proposed Rule Change
1. Purpose
The purpose of the proposed rule change is to reward firms that
meet a minimum average daily displayed volume with lower fees for Non-
Display Usage and the Exchange's 40Gb and 10Gb Ultra high-speed
connection to the Exchange.\3\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\3\ This proposal was initially filed on March 6, 2024, as SR-
Nasdaq-2024-011. On March 20, 2024, that filing was withdrawn and
replaced with SR-Nasdaq-2024-015. On March 22, 2024, SR-Nasdaq-2024-
015 was withdrawn and replaced with the instant filing due to a
technical error.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Non-Display Usage
Non-Display Usage is any method of accessing Nasdaq U.S.
information that involves access or use by a machine or automated
device without access or use of a display by a natural person. Examples
of Non-Display Usage include, but are not limited to:
Automated trading;
Automated order/quote generation and/or order/quote
pegging;
Price referencing for use in algorithmic trading;
Price referencing for use in smart order routing;
Program trading and high frequency trading;
Order verification;
Automated surveillance programs;
Risk management;
Automatic order cancellation, or automatic error
discovery;
Clearing and settlement activities;
Account maintenance (e.g., controlling margin for a
customer account); and
``Hot'' disaster recovery.
Although either top-of-book or depth-of-book data can be used for
Non-Display Usage, the proposal modifies fees for depth-of-book data
only.\4\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\4\ See Equity 7, Section 123 (Nasdaq Depth-of-Book data).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Non-Display fees are currently assessed on a per-subscriber \5\ or
per-firm basis. Monthly fees are $375 per Subscriber for 1-39
subscribers; $15,000 per firm for 40-99 subscribers; $30,000 per firm
for 100-249 subscribers; and $75,000 per firm for 250 or more
subscribers.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\5\ ``Subscriber'' is defined as a device or computer terminal
or an automated service which is entitled to receive information.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Under the proposed rule change, a member firm that meets the
minimum ADV threshold discussed below would continue to pay those fees.
Firms that do not meet the minimum ADV threshold, however, as well
as non-member firms, would pay the new monthly fees of $500 per
subscriber for 1-39 subscribers; $20,000 per firm for 40-99
subscribers; $40,000 per firm for 100-249 subscribers; and $100,000 per
firm for 250 or more subscribers.
Fiber Connections to the Exchange (40Gb and 10Gb Ultra)
Nasdaq offers customers the opportunity to co-locate their servers
and equipment within the Nasdaq Data Center,\6\ allowing participants
an opportunity to reduce latency and network complexity. Nasdaq offers
a variety of connectivity options to fit a firm's specific networking
needs, including the high-speed 40Gb and 10Gb Ultra networks.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\6\ See Nasdaq Co-Location (CoLo) Services, available at https://www.nasdaqtrader.com/trader.aspx?id=colo; Stock Exchange Data
Center & Trading, available at https://www.nasdaq.com/solutions/nasdaq-co-location.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
All of Nasdaq's colocation and connectivity options offer customers
access to any or all Nasdaq exchanges through a single connection.\7\
For example, a firm that is a member of all six Nasdaq exchanges that
purchases services in the Nasdaq Data Center such as a 40G fiber
connection, cabinet space, cooling fans, and patch cables only
purchases these products or services once to use them for all six
Nasdaq exchanges.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\7\ See Securities Exchange Act Release No. 84571 (November 9,
2018), 83 FR 57758 (November 16, 2018) (SR-Nasdaq-2018-086).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Nasdaq currently charges members an ongoing monthly fee of $21,100
for the 40Gb fiber connection and $15,825 for the 10Gb Ultra connection
to the Nasdaq exchanges. Under the proposed rule change, a firm that
meets the minimum ADV threshold would continue to pay those fees.
Member firms that do not meet the minimum ADV threshold discussed
below, as well as non-member firms, would pay the new monthly fee of
$23,700 for the 40Gb fiber connection and $17,800 for the 10Gb Ultra
connection.
Minimum ADV
The proposal introduces the new term ``Minimum ADV,'' which will
mean the introduction by a member of at least one million shares of
added executed displayed liquidity on average per trading day in all
securities through one or more of the member's market participant
identifiers (``MPIDs'') on the Nasdaq Market Center. Average daily
volume is calculated as the total volume of shares executed for all
added
[[Page 24071]]
displayed orders in all securities during the trading month divided by
the number of trading days in that month, averaged over the six-month
period preceding the billing month, or the date the firm became a
member, whichever is shorter. New members will be deemed to meet the
Minimum ADV for the first month of operation. Minimum ADV excludes
sponsored access by a member on behalf of a third party. The minimum
ADV threshold was designed to be accessible to all members to promote
wide engagement with the Exchange.
Nasdaq does not expect any member to be disadvantaged by the
proposal. Nasdaq is a maker-taker platform and, as such, offers rebates
to members that offer displayed liquidity. With these rebates, no
member should have any difficulty posting and executing sufficient
displayed liquidity to meet the ADV threshold. The threshold is,
moreover, set at a level that Nasdaq believes any member--even smaller
members--should be able to meet without significant effort. Because the
threshold applies to displayed liquidity only, the proposal should not
impact the Best Execution obligations of any member. If all members
were to meet this threshold, the proposal would add an incremental 60-
80 million shares to Nasdaq's accessible liquidity.
Non-members that, by definition, do not post displayed liquidity to
the market would pay the higher fees. This is because the non-members
do not directly contribute order flow to the Exchange, but nevertheless
benefit from that order flow through tighter spreads, better prices,
and the other advantages of a more liquid platform, as discussed in
further detail under Statutory Basis.
The Proposal Will Promote Competition Among Trading Venues
Exchanges, like all trading venues, compete as platforms. All
elements of the platform--trade executions, market data, connectivity,
membership, and listings--operate in concert. Trade executions increase
the value of market data; market data functions as an advertisement for
on-exchange trading; listings increase the value of trade executions
and market data; and greater liquidity on the exchange enhances the
value of ports and colocation services.
As discussed under Statutory Basis, we have attached a data-based
analysis demonstrating how platform competition works entitled ``How
Exchanges Compete: An Economic Analysis of Platform Competition'' as
Exhibit 3. The paper explains that exchanges are multi-sided platforms,
whose value is dependent on attracting users to multiple sides of the
platform. Issuers need investors, and every trade requires two sides to
trade. To make its platform attractive to multiple constituencies, an
exchange must consider inter-side externalities, meaning demand for one
set of platform services depends on the demand for other services. This
proposal is designed to promote competition by providing an incentive
for members to provide liquidity (therefore attracting investors and
increasing the overall value of the platform) through charging lower
fees for other platform services (i.e., market data and connectivity).
This will lead to more displayed liquidity on the Exchange, enhancing
and enriching the market data distributed to the industry, which then
increases the amount of interest in the platform. This will also enable
the Exchange to offer investors a more robust, lower cost-trading
experience through tighter spreads and more efficient trading as
discussed in Exhibit 3, placing it in a better competitive position
relative to other exchanges and trading venues.\8\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\8\ To the degree that the additional liquidity is moved from
off-exchange venues to on-exchange platforms, overall market
transparency will improve as well.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
2. Statutory Basis
The Exchange believes that its proposal is consistent with Section
6(b) of the Act,\9\ in general, and furthers the objectives of Sections
6(b)(4) and 6(b)(5) of the Act,\10\ in particular, in that it provides
for the equitable allocation of reasonable dues, fees, and other
charges among members and issuers and other persons using any facility,
and is not designed to permit unfair discrimination between customers,
issuers, brokers, or dealers.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\9\ 15 U.S.C. 78f(b).
\10\ 15 U.S.C. 78f(b)(4) and (5).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Fees Produced in a Competitive Environment Are an Equitable Allocation
of Reasonable Dues, Fees, and Other Charges
Reliance on competitive solutions is fundamental to the Act. Where
significant competitive forces constrain fees, fee levels meet the
Act's standard for the ``equitable allocation of reasonable dues, fees,
and other charges among members and issuers and other persons using its
facilities,'' \11\ unless there is a substantial countervailing basis
to find that a fee does not meet some other requirement of the Act.\12\
Evidence of platform competition demonstrates that each exchange
product is sold in a competitive environment, and its fees will be an
equitable allocation of reasonable dues, fees, and other charges,
provided that nothing about the product or its fee structure impairs
competition.\13\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\11\ See 15 U.S.C. 78f(b)(4).
\12\ See U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission, ``Staff
Guidance on SRO Rule filings Relating to Fees'' (May 21, 2019),
available at https://www.sec.gov/tm/staff-guidance-sro-rule-filings-fees (``Fee Guidance'') (``If significant competitive forces
constrain the fee at issue, fee levels will be presumed to be fair
and reasonable, and the inquiry is whether there is a substantial
countervailing basis to find that the fee terms nevertheless fail to
meet an applicable requirement of the Exchange Act (e.g., that fees
are equitably allocated, not unfairly discriminatory, and not an
undue burden on competition).'').
\13\ Nothing in the Act requires proof of product-by-product
competition.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Congress directed the Commission to ``rely on `competition,
whenever possible, in meeting its regulatory responsibilities for
overseeing the SROs and the national market system.' '' \14\ Following
this mandate, the Commission and the courts have repeatedly expressed
their preference for competition over regulatory intervention to
determine prices, products, and services in the securities markets.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\14\ NetCoalition v. SEC, 715 F.3d 342, 534-35 (D.C. Cir. 2013);
see also H.R. Rep. No. 94-229 at 92 (1975) (``[I]t is the intent of
the conferees that the national market system evolve through the
interplay of competitive forces as unnecessary regulatory
restrictions are removed.'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
In Regulation NMS, the Commission highlighted the importance of
market forces in determining prices and SRO revenues and recognized
that regulation of the national market system ``has been remarkably
successful in promoting market competition in its broader forms that
are most important to investors and listed companies.'' \15\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\15\ See Securities Exchange Act Release No. 51808 (June 9,
2005), 70 FR 37496, 37499 (June 29, 2005) (``Regulation NMS Adopting
Release'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
As a result, the Commission has long relied on competitive forces
to determine whether a fee proposal is equitable, fair, reasonable, and
not unreasonably or unfairly discriminatory. In 2008, the Commission
explained that ``[i]f competitive forces are operative, the self-
interest of the exchanges themselves will work powerfully to constrain
unreasonable or unfair behavior.'' \16\ In 2019, Commission Staff
reaffirmed that ``[i]f significant competitive forces constrain the fee
at issue, fee levels will be presumed to be fair and reasonable . . .
.'' \17\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\16\ See Securities Exchange Act Release No. 59039 (December 2,
2008), 73 FR 74770 (December 9, 2008) (SR-NYSEArca-2006-21).
\17\ See Fee Guidance, supra n.10.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Accordingly, ``the existence of significant competition provides a
substantial basis for finding that the terms of an exchange's fee
proposal are equitable, fair, reasonable, and not
[[Page 24072]]
unreasonably or unfairly discriminatory.'' \18\ Consistent with the
Commission's longstanding focus on competition, Commission Staff have
indicated that they would only look at factors outside of the
competitive market if a ``proposal lacks persuasive evidence that the
proposed fee is constrained by significant competitive forces.'' \19\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\18\ See id.
\19\ See id. In the Fee Guidance, the Staff indicated that
``[w]hen reviewing rule filing proposals . . . [it] is mindful of
recent opinions by the D.C. Circuit,'' including Susquehanna
International Group, LLP v. SEC, 866 F.3d 442 (D.C. Cir. 2017).
However, the D.C. Circuit's decision in Susquehanna is irrelevant to
the Commission's review of immediately effective SRO fee filings.
Susquehanna involved the Commission's approval of a rule proposed
under Section 19(b)(2) of the Act, not its evaluation of whether to
temporarily suspend an SRO's immediately effective fee filing under
Section 19(b)(3). A comparison of Sections 19(b)(2) and 19(b)(3) of
the Act makes clear that the Commission is not required to undertake
the same independent review, and make the same findings and
determinations, for Section 19(b)(3) filings that it must for
Section 19(b)(2) filings. In particular, Section 19(b)(2) requires
the Commission to ``find[ ] that [a] proposed rule change is
consistent with the'' Act before approving the rule. 15 U.S.C.
78s(b)(2)(C)(i). Section 19(b)(3), by contrast, imbues the
Commission with discretion, stating that it ``may temporarily
suspend'' an immediately effective rule filing where ``it appears to
the Commission that such action is necessary or appropriate.'' As
the Supreme Court has explained, statutes stating that an agency
``may''--but need not--take certain action are ``written in the
language of permission and discretion.'' S. Ry. Co. v. Seaboard
Allied Milling, 442 U.S. 444, 455 (1979); see also Crooker v. SEC,
161 F.2d 944, 949 (1st Cir. 1947) (per curiam). The ``contrast''
between Sections 19(b)(2) and 19(b)(3), the Commission itself has
explained, ``reflects the fundamental difference in the way Congress
intended for different types of rules to be treated.'' Brief of
Respondent SEC, NetCoalition v. SEC, 715 F.3d 342 (D.C. Cir. 2013)
(Nos. 10-1421 et al.); see also id. at 42-43 (``[W]hile the
Commission's authority to suspend a fee under Subsection (3)(C) is
permissive, its duties under Subsection (2) are stated in mandatory
terms.''). Thus, neither Susquehanna, nor Section 19(b)(3) of the
Act, requires the Commission to make independent findings that an
immediately effective SRO fee filing such as this one is consistent
with the Act. To the degree that the Susquehanna decision is
applicable to any Commission action, however, the court held that
the Commission is required to ``itself find or determine'' that a
proposal meets statutory requirements, explaining that the
Commission is ``obligated to make an independent review'' of an
SRO's proposal, and not rely solely on the work of the SRO. See 866
F.3d at 446.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Nothing in the Act Requires an Examination of Fees in Isolation
The Act mandates the ``equitable allocation of reasonable dues,
fees, and other charges among members and issuers and other persons
using its facilities.'' \20\ This provision refers generally to
``reasonable dues, fees, and other charges'' as a whole, not individual
fees. Nothing in the Act requires the individual examination of
specific product fees in isolation. Provided that a proposed rule
change does not in and of itself undermine competition, evidence of
platform competition is sufficient to show that the product operates in
a competitive environment.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\20\ See 15 U.S.C. 78f(b)(4).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
A determination of whether a proposal permits unfair discrimination
between customers, issuers, brokers, or dealers remains a separate
product-specific inquiry.
The Commission Has Recognized That Exchanges Are Subject to Significant
Competitive Forces in the Market for Order Flow
The fact that the market for order flow is competitive has long
been recognized by the courts. In NetCoalition v. Securities and
Exchange Commission, the D.C. Circuit stated, ``[n]o one disputes that
competition for order flow is `fierce.' . . . As the SEC explained,
`[i]n the U.S. national market system, buyers and sellers of
securities, and the broker-dealers that act as their order-routing
agents, have a wide range of choices of where to route orders for
execution'; [and] `no exchange can afford to take its market share
percentages for granted' because `no exchange possesses a monopoly,
regulatory or otherwise, in the execution of order flow from broker
dealers.' '' \21\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\21\ See NetCoalition, 615 F.3d at 539 (D.C. Cir. 2010) (quoting
Securities Exchange Act Release No. 59039 (December 2, 2008), 73 FR
74770, 74782-83 (December 9, 2008) (SR-NYSEArca-2006-21)).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
All Exchange Products Are Subject to Competition--Not Just Those
Directly Related to Order Flow
As discussed more fully in our analysis, ``How Exchanges Compete:
An Economic Analysis of Platform Competition'' (Exhibit 3), competition
is not limited to order flow. Data shows that the combination of
explicit all-in costs to trade and other implicit costs has largely
equalized the cost to trade across venues.\22\ This is a function of
the fact that, if the all-in cost to the user of interacting with an
exchange exceeds market price, customers can and do shift their
purchases and trading activity to other exchanges, and therefore the
exchange must adjust one or more of its fees to attract customers.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\22\ Competition across platforms constrains platform fees and
results in ``all-in'' costs becoming equal across platforms. The
Staff Guidance on SRO Rule Filings Relating to Fees, however, states
that platform competition requires that the ``overall return of the
platform, rather than the return of any particular fees charged to a
type of customer, . . . be used to assess the competitiveness of the
platform's market,'' and that ``[a]n SRO that wishes to rely on
total platform theory must provide evidence demonstrating that
competitive forces are sufficient to constrain the SRO's aggregate
return across the platform.'' See Fee Guidance, supra n.10 (emphasis
added). We do not know, and cannot determine, whether returns (as
opposed to fees) are equalized across platforms, because we do not
have detailed cost information from other exchanges. An analysis of
returns, however, is unnecessary to show that competition constrains
fees given that, as we demonstrate below, platform competition can
be demonstrated solely by examining costs to users.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
This conclusion is particularly striking given that different
exchanges engage in a variety of business models and offer an array of
pricing options to appeal to different customer types. The largest
exchanges operate maker-taker platforms, offering rebates to attract
trading liquidity, which allows them to maintain actionable quotes with
high liquidity and offer high-quality market data. The negative price
charged to liquidity providers through rebates is part of the platform
because it serves to create features attractive to other participants,
including oftentimes tight spreads, actionable and lit quotes, and more
valuable market data.
Inverted venues, in contrast, have the opposite price structure--
liquidity providers pay to add liquidity, while liquidity takers earn a
rebate. These platforms offer less liquidity, but better queue
priority, faster fills, and lower effective spreads for investors.
There are a wide range of other pricing models and product offerings
among the dozens of lit and unlit trading venues that compete in the
marketplace in addition to these examples.
The different strategies among exchanges also manifest in the
pricing of other services, such as market data and connectivity. Some
exchanges charge for such services, while others charge little or
nothing (typically because the exchange is new or has little
liquidity), just as some exchanges charge a fee per trade, while others
pay rebates.
In assessing competition for exchange services, we must consider
not only explicit costs, such as fees for trading, market data, and
connectivity, but also the implicit costs of trading on an exchange.
The realized spread, or markout, captures the implicit cost to trade on
a platform.
The concept of markout was created by market makers trying to
capture the spread while providing a two-sided (bid and offer) market.
For market makers, being filled on the bid or the offer can cause a
loss if the fill changes market prices. For example, a fill on a market
maker's bid just as the stock price falls results in a ``virtual
loss,'' because the market maker has a long position with a new bid
lower than the fill.
Negative markouts can be beneficial. For example, if an
institutional investor is working a large buy order, negative markouts
represent fills as the market
[[Page 24073]]
falls, allowing later orders to be placed sooner, and likely at a
better price, reducing the opportunity costs as well as explicit cost
of building the position.
Data suggests that market participants employ sophisticated
analytic tools to weigh the cost of immediate liquidity and lower
opportunity costs against better spread capture (lower markouts) and
explicit trading costs. As discussed in greater detail in Exhibit 3,
the venues with the highest explicit costs--typically inverted and fee-
fee venues--have the lowest implicit costs from markouts and vice
versa. Higher positive markouts mean more spread capture, but those
venues also tend to have the highest explicit costs, and provide the
least liquidity, and positive externalities, to the market.
Considering both the explicit costs charged by exchanges for their
various joint products and the implicit costs incurred by traders to
trade on various exchanges, the data show that all-in trading costs
across exchanges are largely equalized, regardless of different trading
strategies offered by each platform for each individual service.
As such, platform competition has resulted in a competitive
environment in the market for exchange services, in which trading
platforms are constrained by other platforms' offerings, taking into
consideration the all-in cost of interacting with the platform. This
constraint is a natural consequence of competition and demonstrates
that no exchange platform can charge excessive fees and expect to
remain competitive, thereby constraining fees on all products sold as
part of the platform. The existence of platform-level competition also
explains why some consumers route orders to the exchange with the
highest explicit trading costs even though other exchanges offer free
or a net rebate for trading.\23\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\23\ Empirical evidence also shows that market data is more
valuable from exchanges with more liquidity. Many customers decide
not to take data from smaller markets, even though they are free or
much lower cost than larger markets.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Exchanges Compete at Both the Platform and Product Level
Exchange customers are differentiated in the value they place on
the different products offered by exchanges and in their willingness to
pay for those products. This occurs both on a firm-wide and a
transaction basis; for example, individual customers ``multi-home'' on
various platforms, and are thus able to route different trades to
different platforms to take advantage of favorable economics offered on
a trade-to-trade basis.
Exchanges compete by offering differentiated packages of pricing
and products to attract different categories of customer. As in any
competitive market, consumers will ``vote with their feet,''
incentivizing platforms to supply an array of pricing and product
offerings that suit diverse consumer needs far more effectively than a
uniform, one-size-fits-some rigid product offering. If an exchange's
pricing for a particular product gets out of line, such that its total
return is boosted above competitive levels, market forces will
discipline that approach because competing exchanges will quickly
attract customer volume through more attractive all-in trading costs.
In addition, if a particular package of pricing and products is not
attractive to a sufficient volume of customers in a particular
category, those customers may elect not to purchase the service. This
is why exchanges compete at a product level, as well as based on all-in
trading costs.
Exchanges Compete With Off-Exchange Trading Platforms in Addition to
Other Exchanges
As the SEC recently noted in its market infrastructure
proposal,\24\ the number of transactions completed on non-exchange
venues has been growing. Allowing exchanges to compete as platforms
will help exchanges compete against non-exchange venues, and, to the
degree order flow is shifted from non-exchange to exchange venues,
overall market transparency will improve.\25\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\24\ See Regulation NMS: Minimum Pricing Increments, Access
Fees, and Transparency of Better Price Orders, Securities Exchange
Act Release No. 96494 (File No. S7-30-22), available at https://www.sec.gov/rules/proposed/2022/34-96494.pdf.
\25\ Non-exchange venues rely on market data distributed by
exchanges to set prices. Greater transparency allows both exchange
and non-exchange venues to operate more effectively and efficiently.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Exchanges have a unique role to play in market transparency because
they publish an array of pre- and post-trade data that non-exchange
venues, almost entirely, do not. Greater transparency benefits non-
exchange venues by enabling them to provide more accurate pricing to
their customers, and by helping such venues set their own prices,
benchmark, analyze the total cost of ownership, and assess their own
trading strategies.
Allowing exchanges to compete effectively as platforms has other
positive network effects. Larger trading platforms offer lower average
trading costs. As trading platforms attract more liquidity, bid-ask
spreads tighten, search costs fall (by limiting the number of venues
that a customer needs to check to assess the market), and connection
costs decrease, as customers have no need to connect to all venues.\26\
The whole is therefore greater (in the sense that it is more efficient)
than the sum of the parts.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\26\ In addition, Nasdaq's experience shows that fewer customers
connect with smaller trading venues than with larger venues.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
This is not to say that smaller established trading platforms do
not have a role to play. They provide specialized services that cater
to individual customer needs. These specialized services help the
smaller exchanges grow by driving liquidity to their platforms, and, if
they are successful, achieve the economies of scale that benefit the
larger enterprises. Because the total costs of interacting with an
exchange are roughly equal, smaller exchanges offset higher trading
costs with lower connectivity, market data, or other fees. While the
mix of fees will change as exchanges grow, the all-in cost of
interacting with the exchange remains roughly the same.
Acknowledging that exchanges compete as platforms and approving
fees expeditiously on that basis will improve the ability of exchanges
to compete against non-exchange venues, and, to the degree order flow
is shifted to exchanges, both transparency and efficiency will improve.
The Proposed Fees Are Equitable and Reasonable Because They Will Be
Subject to Competition
This proposal offers member firms an incentive to display liquidity
through lower non-display and connectivity fees. The intent is to
generate a ``virtuous cycle,'' in which the proposed fee structure will
attract more liquidity to the Exchange, making it a more attractive
trading venue, and thereby attracting more liquidity.
Incentive programs have been widely adopted by exchanges, and are
reasonable, equitable, and non-discriminatory because they are open on
an equal basis to similarly situated members and provide additional
benefits or discounts that are reasonably related to the value to an
exchange's market quality and activity.\27\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\27\ See, e.g., Securities Exchange Act Release No. 92493 (July
26, 2021), 86 FR 41129 (July 30, 2021) (SR-CboeEDGX-2021-034)
(proposal to provide discount to new members that meet certain
volume thresholds, noting that ``relative volume-based incentives
and discounts have been widely adopted by exchanges . . . and are
reasonable, equitable and non-discriminatory because they are open
on an equal basis to similarly situated members and provide
additional benefits or discounts that are reasonably related to (i)
the value to an exchange's market quality and (ii) associated higher
levels of market activity . . . .'') (not suspended by Commission);
see also Securities Exchange Act Release No. 53790 (May 11, 2006),
71 FR 28738 (May 17, 2006) (SR-Phlx-2006-04) (``The Commission
recognizes that volume-based discounts of fees are not uncommon, and
where the discount can be applied objectively, it is consistent with
Rule 603. For the same reasons noted above, the Commission believes
that the fee structure meets the standard in section 6(b)(4) of the
Act in that the proposed rule change provides for the equitable
allocation of reasonable dues, fees, and other charges among the
Exchange's members and issuers and other persons using its
facilities.'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
[[Page 24074]]
The proposal will contribute to market quality because it will help
bring new order flow to the Exchange. Greater displayed liquidity on
the Exchange offers investors deeper, more liquid markets and execution
opportunities.
Increased order flow benefits investors by deepening the Exchange's
liquidity pool, potentially providing greater execution incentives and
opportunities, offering additional flexibility for all investors to
enjoy cost savings, supporting the quality of price discovery,
promoting market transparency, and lowering spreads between bids and
offers and thereby lowering investor costs. To the degree that
liquidity is attracted from dark venues, that liquidity also increases
transparency for the market overall, providing investors with more
information about market trends.
The proposal will help members that meet the minimum ADV threshold
maintain lower costs and will benefit them through the many positive
externalities associated with a more liquid exchange.
The competition among exchanges as trading platforms, as well as
the competition between exchanges and alternative trading venues,
constrain exchanges from charging excessive fees for any exchange
products, including trading, listings, ports, and market data. Indeed,
the fees that arise from the competition among trading platforms may be
too low because they fail to reflect the benefits to the market as a
whole of exchange products and services, allowing other venues to free-
ride on these investments by the exchange platforms, increasing
fragmentation and search costs.
As long as total returns are constrained by competitive forces--as
demonstrated in detail by the report provided as Exhibit 3--there is no
regulatory basis to be concerned with pricing of particular elements
offered on a platform. Indeed, regulatory constraints in this
environment are likely to reduce consumer welfare by constraining
certain exchanges from offering packages of pricing and products that
would be attractive to certain sets of consumers, thus impeding
competition with venues that are not subject to the same regulatory
limitations and reducing the benefits of competition to customers.
The Proposal Is Not Unfairly Discriminatory
The proposal is not unfairly discriminatory. Non-Display Usage and
the Exchange's 40Gb and 10Gb Ultra high-speed connections will be
offered to all members and non-members on like terms. It is also not
unfair to charge more to firms that do not directly contribute order
flow to the Exchange, but nevertheless benefit from that order flow
through tighter spreads, better prices, and the other advantages of a
more liquid platform.
Specifically, the proposal is not unfairly discriminatory with
respect to either members or non-members.
With respect to members, all members that meet the ADV threshold
will be charged lower fees. With respect to smaller members, Nasdaq
offers rebates to members that offer displayed liquidity. With these
rebates, any member--even smaller members--should have the ability to
post sufficient displayed liquidity to meet the ADV threshold.
The proposal is not unfairly discriminatory with respect to non-
members broker-dealers, which include brokers routing trades through
members and off-exchange trading platforms that use exchange data to
execute trades, because they have the option of becoming members to
obtain lower fees under the proposal, and because they realize the
benefits of higher liquidity--including tighter spreads and better
prices--and it is not unfair discrimination to charge a higher fee for
that benefit.
The proposal is not unfairly discriminatory with respect to non-
member firms that are not broker-dealers, such as market data vendors
and index providers, because they also benefit from the value that the
additional liquidity generated by this proposal will provide to the
trading platform. As noted above, incentivizing higher levels of
liquidity enhances and enriches the market data distributed to the
industry, and increases the overall value of platform. It is not unfair
for such parties to pay a higher fee to reflect the greater value of
the platform.
Discounts for specific categories of market participants are well-
established; examples include non-professional fees, broker-dealer
enterprise licenses, and a media enterprise license.\28\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\28\ See, e.g., The Nasdaq Stock Market, Price List--U.S.
Equities, available at https://www.nasdaqtrader.com/Trader.aspx?id=DPUSData (providing discounts for Non-Professional
subscribers for Nasdaq TotalView and other market data products,
enterprise licenses for broker-dealers for multiple market data
products, and a digital media enterprise license for Nasdaq Basic).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
For all of the foregoing reasons, the Exchange believes that the
proposal is consistent with the Act.
B. Self-Regulatory Organization's Statement on Burden on Competition
In accordance with Section 6(b)(8) of the Act,\29\ the Exchange
believes that the proposed rule change will not impose any burden on
competition that is not necessary or appropriate in furtherance of the
purposes of the Act.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\29\ 15 U.S.C. 78f(b)(8).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Rather, as discussed above, the Exchange believes that the proposed
changes would increase competition by attracting additional liquidity
to the Exchange, which the Exchange believes will enhance market
quality, thereby promoting market depth, price discovery, and
transparency and enhancing order execution opportunities for member
organizations. As a result, the Exchange believes that the proposed
change furthers the Commission's goal in adopting Regulation NMS of
fostering integrated competition among orders, which promotes ``more
efficient pricing of individual stocks for all types of orders, large
and small.'' \30\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\30\ Securities Exchange Act Release No. 51808, 70 FR 37496,
37498-99 (June 29, 2005) (Regulation NMS).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Intra-market Competition. Nothing in the proposal burdens intra-
market competition (the competition among consumers of exchange data)
because the proposed fee structure would be available to all similarly
situated market participants, and, as such, the proposed change would
not impose a disparate burden on different market participants.
Intermarket Competition. Nothing in the proposal burdens
intermarket competition (the competition among self-regulatory
organizations) because competitors are free to modify their own fees in
response.
As previously discussed, the Exchange operates in a highly
competitive market. Members have numerous alternative venues that they
may participate on and direct their order flow to, including other
equities exchanges, off-exchange venues, and alternative trading
systems. Participants can readily choose to send their orders to other
exchange and off-exchange venues if they deem fee levels at those
[[Page 24075]]
other venues to be more favorable. In such an environment, the Exchange
must continually adjust its fees and rebates to remain competitive with
other exchanges and with off-exchange venues.
C. Self-Regulatory Organization's Statement on Comments on the Proposed
Rule Change Received From Members, Participants, or Others
No written comments were either solicited or received.
III. Date of Effectiveness of the Proposed Rule Change and Timing for
Commission Action
The foregoing rule change has become effective pursuant to Section
19(b)(3)(A)(ii) of the Act.\31\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\31\ 15 U.S.C. 78s(b)(3)(A)(ii).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
At any time within 60 days of the filing of the proposed rule
change, the Commission summarily may temporarily suspend such rule
change if it appears to the Commission that such action is: (i)
necessary or appropriate in the public interest; (ii) for the
protection of investors; or (iii) otherwise in furtherance of the
purposes of the Act. If the Commission takes such action, the
Commission shall institute proceedings to determine whether the
proposed rule should be approved or disapproved.
IV. Solicitation of Comments
Interested persons are invited to submit written data, views and
arguments concerning the foregoing, including whether the proposed rule
change is consistent with the Act. Comments may be submitted by any of
the following methods:
Electronic Comments
Use the Commission's internet comment form (https://www.sec.gov/rules/sro.shtml); or
Send an email to [email protected]. Please include
file number SR-NASDAQ-2024-016 on the subject line.
Paper Comments
Send paper comments in triplicate to Secretary, Securities
and Exchange Commission, 100 F Street NE, Washington, DC 20549-1090.
All submissions should refer to file number SR-NASDAQ-2024-016. This
file number should be included on the subject line if email is used. To
help the Commission process and review your comments more efficiently,
please use only one method. The Commission will post all comments on
the Commission's internet website (https://www.sec.gov/rules/sro.shtml). Copies of the submission, all subsequent amendments, all
written statements with respect to the proposed rule change that are
filed with the Commission, and all written communications relating to
the proposed rule change between the Commission and any person, other
than those that may be withheld from the public in accordance with the
provisions of 5 U.S.C. 552, will be available for website viewing and
printing in the Commission's Public Reference Room, 100 F Street NE,
Washington, DC 20549, on official business days between the hours of 10
a.m. and 3 p.m. Copies of the filing also will be available for
inspection and copying at the principal office of the Exchange. Do not
include personal identifiable information in submissions; you should
submit only information that you wish to make available publicly. We
may redact in part or withhold entirely from publication submitted
material that is obscene or subject to copyright protection. All
submissions should refer to file number SR-NASDAQ-2024-016 and should
be submitted on or before April 26, 2024.
For the Commission, by the Division of Trading and Markets,
pursuant to delegated authority.\32\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\32\ 17 CFR 200.30-3(a)(12).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
J. Matthew DeLesDernier,
Deputy Secretary.
[FR Doc. 2024-07227 Filed 4-4-24; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 8011-01-P