Self-Regulatory Organizations; NYSE MKT LLC; Notice of Filing and Immediate Effectiveness of Proposed Rule Change To Amend Market Data Fees for the NYSE Amex Options Product, 3225-3229 [2016-00900]
Download as PDF
Federal Register / Vol. 81, No. 12 / Wednesday, January 20, 2016 / Notices
Committee. This Sunshine Act notice is
being issued because a quorum of the
Commission may attend the meeting.
The agenda for the meeting includes:
remarks from Commissioners; a
discussion of fixed income market
structure and pre-trade price
transparency; a discussion of a draft
letter from the Investor as Owner
subcommittee regarding Financial
Accounting Standards Board proposed
amendments to the Statement of
Financial Accounting Concepts and
Notes to Financial Statements
concerning disclosure materiality; an
update on crowdfunding rules; a
discussion of NASDAQ listing
standards—shareholder approval rules;
subcommittee reports; and a nonpublic
administrative work session during
lunch.
For further information, please
contact the Office of the Secretary at
(202) 551–5400.
Dated: January 14, 2016.
Brent J. Fields,
Secretary.
[FR Doc. 2016–01129 Filed 1–15–16; 4:15 pm]
BILLING CODE 8011–01–P
[Release No. 34–76889; File No. SR–
NYSEMKT–2015–113]
tkelley on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
January 13, 2016.
Pursuant to section 19(b)(1) 1 of the
Securities Exchange Act of 1934 (the
‘‘Act’’) 2 and Rule 19b–4 thereunder,3
notice is hereby given that, on December
31, 2015, NYSE MKT LLC (the
‘‘Exchange’’ or ‘‘NYSE MKT’’) filed with
the Securities and Exchange
Commission (the ‘‘Commission’’) the
proposed rule change as described in
Items I, II, and III below, which Items
have been prepared by the selfregulatory organization. The
Commission is publishing this notice to
solicit comments on the proposed rule
change from interested persons.
U.S.C. 78s(b)(1).
U.S.C. 78a.
3 17 CFR 240.19b–4.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:12 Jan 19, 2016
Jkt 238001
II. Self-Regulatory Organization’s
Statement of the Purpose of, and
Statutory Basis for, the Proposed Rule
Change
In its filing with the Commission, the
self-regulatory organization included
statements concerning the purpose of,
and basis for, the proposed rule change
and discussed any comments it received
on the proposed rule change. The text
of those statements may be examined at
the places specified in Item IV below.
The Exchange has prepared summaries,
set forth in sections A, B, and C below,
of the most significant parts of such
statements.
1. Purpose
Self-Regulatory Organizations; NYSE
MKT LLC; Notice of Filing and
Immediate Effectiveness of Proposed
Rule Change To Amend Market Data
Fees for the NYSE Amex Options
Product
2 15
The Exchange proposes to amend the
fees for NYSE Amex Options Product,4
as set forth on the NYSE Amex Options
Proprietary Market Data Fee Schedule
(‘‘Fee Schedule’’). The Exchange
proposes to establish a multiple data
feed fee effective January 1, 2016. The
text of the proposed rule change is
available on the Exchange’s Web site at
www.nyse.com, at the principal office of
the Exchange, and at the Commission’s
Public Reference Room.
A. Self-Regulatory Organization’s
Statement of the Purpose of, and
Statutory Basis for, the Proposed Rule
Change
SECURITIES AND EXCHANGE
COMMISSION
1 15
I. Self-Regulatory Organization’s
Statement of the Terms of the Substance
of the Proposed Rule Change
The Exchange proposes to amend the
fees for NYSE Amex Options Product,5
as set forth on the NYSE Amex Options
Proprietary Market Data Fee Schedule
(‘‘Fee Schedule’’). The Exchange
proposes to establish a multiple data
feed fee effective January 1, 2016.
Specifically, the Exchange proposes to
establish a new monthly fee, the
‘‘Multiple Data Feed Fee,’’ that would
apply to data recipients that take a data
feed for NYSE Amex Options Product in
more than two locations. Data recipients
taking NYSE Amex Options Product in
more than two locations would be
charged $200 per additional location per
4 See Securities Exchange Act Release Nos. 76022
(Sept. 29, 2015), 80 FR 60201 (Oct. 5, 2015) (SR–
NYSEMKT–2015–68) (Notice). The single fee for the
NYSE Amex Options Product set forth on the Fee
Schedule is comprised of three data feeds: Amex
Options Top, Amex Options Deep, and Amex
Options Complex.
5 See Securities Exchange Act Release Nos. 76022
(Sept. 29, 2015), 80 FR 60201 (Oct. 5, 2015) (SR–
NYSEMKT–2015–68) (Notice). The single fee for the
NYSE Amex Options Product set forth on the Fee
Schedule is comprised of three data feeds: Amex
Options Top, Amex Options Deep, and Amex
Options Complex.
PO 00000
Frm 00132
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
3225
product per month. No new reporting
would be required.6
2. Statutory Basis
The Exchange believes that the
proposed rule change is consistent with
the provisions of section 6 of the Act,7
in general, and sections 6(b)(4) and
6(b)(5) of the Act,8 in particular, in that
it provides an equitable allocation of
reasonable fees among users and
recipients of the data and is not
designed to permit unfair
discrimination among customers,
issuers, and brokers.
The fees are also equitable and not
unfairly discriminatory because they
will apply to all data recipients that
choose to subscribe to NYSE Amex
Options Product.
The Exchange believes that it is
reasonable to require data recipients to
pay a modest additional fee taking a
data feed for a market data product in
more than two locations, because such
data recipients can derive substantial
value from being able to consume the
product in as many locations as they
want. In addition, there are
administrative burdens associated with
tracking each location at which a data
recipient receives the product. The
Multiple Data Feed Fee is designed to
encourage data recipients to better
manage their requests for additional
data feeds and to monitor their usage of
data feeds. The proposed fee is designed
to apply to data feeds received in more
than two locations so that each data
recipient can have one primary and one
backup data location before having to
pay a multiple data feed fee. The
Exchange notes that this pricing is
consistent with similar pricing adopted
in 2013 by the Consolidated Tape
Association (‘‘CTA’’).9 The Exchange
also notes that the OPRA Plan imposes
a similar charge of $100 per connection
for circuit connections in addition to the
primary and backup connections.10
The Exchange notes that NYSE Amex
Options Product is entirely optional.
6 Data vendors currently report a unique Vendor
Account Number for each location at which they
provide a data feed to a data recipient. The
Exchange considers each Vendor Account Number
a location. For example, if a data recipient has five
Vendor Account Numbers, representing five
locations, for the receipt of the NYSE Amex Options
Product, that data recipient will pay the Multiple
Data Feed fee with respect to three of the five
locations, or $600.
7 15 U.S.C. 78f(b).
8 15 U.S.C. 78f(b)(4), (5).
9 See Securities Exchange Act Release No. 70010
(July 19, 2013), 78 FR 44984 (July 25, 2013) (SR–
CTA/CQ–2013–04).
10 See ‘‘Direct Access Fee,’’ Options Price
Reporting Authority Fee Schedule Fee Schedule
PRA Plan at https://www.opradata.com/pdf/fee_
schedule.pdf
E:\FR\FM\20JAN1.SGM
20JAN1
3226
Federal Register / Vol. 81, No. 12 / Wednesday, January 20, 2016 / Notices
The Exchange is not required to make
NYSE Amex Options Product available
or to offer any specific pricing
alternatives to any customers, nor is any
firm required to purchase NYSE Amex
Options Product. Firms that do
purchase NYSE Amex Options Product
do so for the primary goals of using it
to increase revenues, reduce expenses,
and in some instances compete directly
with the Exchange (including for order
flow); those firms are able to determine
for themselves whether NYSE Amex
Options Product or any other similar
products are attractively priced or not.
Firms that do not wish to purchase
NYSE Amex Options Product have a
variety of alternative market data
products from which to choose,11 or if
NYSE Amex Options Product does not
provide sufficient value to firms as
offered based on the uses those firms
have or planned to make of it, such
firms may simply choose to conduct
their business operations in ways that
do not use NYSE Amex Options Product
or use it at different levels or in different
configurations. The Exchange notes that
broker-dealers are not required to
purchase proprietary market data to
comply with their best execution
obligations.12
The decision of the United States
Court of Appeals for the District of
Columbia Circuit in NetCoalition v.
SEC, 615 F.3d 525 (D.C. Cir. 2010),
upheld reliance by the Securities and
Exchange Commission (‘‘Commission’’)
upon the existence of competitive
market mechanisms to set reasonable
and equitably allocated fees for
proprietary market data:
tkelley on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
In fact, the legislative history indicates that
the Congress intended that the market system
‘evolve through the interplay of competitive
forces as unnecessary regulatory restrictions
are removed’ and that the SEC wield its
regulatory power ‘in those situations where
competition may not be sufficient,’ such as
11 For example, Chicago Board Options Exchange
(‘‘CBOE’’) charges, for its ‘‘Complex Order Book
Feed,’’ a Distributor Fee of $3,000 per month, a
Professional User Fee of $25 per month and a NonProfessional User Fee of $1 per month. See the
CBOE ‘‘Complex Order Book Feed’’ product and
pricing information, available at https://
www.cboe.org/MDX/CSM/OBOOKMain.aspx.
NASDAQ OMX PHLX LLC (‘‘PHLX’’) also offers a
market data product entitled ‘‘PHLX Orders,’’
which includes order and last sale information for
complex strategies and other market data, and
charges a $3,000 internal monthly fee ($3,500 for
external), $2,000 per Distributor and $500 per
subscriber. See PHLX ‘‘PHLX Orders’’ market data
product and pricing information, available at
https://www.nasdaqtrader.com/
Micro.aspx?id=PHLXOrders and https://
www.nasdaqtrader.com/
Trader.aspx?id=DPPriceListOptions#PHLX,
respectively.
12 See FINRA Regulatory Notice 15–46, ‘‘Best
Execution,’’ November 2015.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:12 Jan 19, 2016
Jkt 238001
in the creation of a ‘consolidated
transactional reporting system.’
Id. at 535 (quoting H.R. Rep. No. 94–229
at 92 (1975), as reprinted in 1975
U.S.C.C.A.N. 323). The court agreed
with the Commission’s conclusion that
‘‘Congress intended that ‘competitive
forces should dictate the services and
practices that constitute the U.S.
national market system for trading
equity securities.’ ’’ 13
As explained below in the Exchange’s
Statement on Burden on Competition,
the Exchange believes that there is
substantial evidence of competition in
the marketplace for proprietary market
data and that the Commission can rely
upon such evidence in concluding that
the fees established in this filing are the
product of competition and therefore
satisfy the relevant statutory
standards.14 In addition, the existence of
alternatives to these data products, such
as options data from other sources, as
described below, further ensures that
the Exchange cannot set unreasonable
fees, or fees that are unreasonably
discriminatory, when vendors and
subscribers can select such alternatives.
As the NetCoalition decision noted,
the Commission is not required to
undertake a cost-of-service or
ratemaking approach. The Exchange
believes that, even if it were possible as
a matter of economic theory, cost-based
pricing for proprietary market data
would be so complicated that it could
not be done practically or offer any
significant benefits.15
13 NetCoalition,
615 F.3d at 535.
916 of the Dodd-Frank Wall Street
Reform and Consumer Protection Act of 2010 (the
‘‘Dodd-Frank Act’’) amended paragraph (A) of
section 19(b)(3) of the Act, 15 U.S.C. 78s(b)(3), to
make clear that all exchange fees for market data
may be filed by exchanges on an immediately
effective basis.
15 The Exchange believes that cost-based pricing
would be impractical because it would create
enormous administrative burdens for all parties and
the Commission to cost-regulate a large number of
participants and standardize and analyze
extraordinary amounts of information, accounts,
and reports. In addition, and as described below, it
is impossible to regulate market data prices in
isolation from prices charged by markets for other
services that are joint products. Cost-based rate
regulation would also lead to litigation and may
distort incentives, including those to minimize
costs and to innovate, leading to further waste.
Under cost-based pricing, the Commission would
be burdened with determining a fair rate of return,
and the industry could experience frequent rate
increases based on escalating expense levels. Even
in industries historically subject to utility
regulation, cost-based ratemaking has been
discredited. As such, the Exchange believes that
cost-based ratemaking would be inappropriate for
proprietary market data and inconsistent with
Congress’s direction that the Commission use its
authority to foster the development of the national
market system, and that market forces will continue
to provide appropriate pricing discipline. See
Appendix C to NYSE’s comments to the
14 Section
PO 00000
Frm 00133
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
For these reasons, the Exchange
believes that the proposed fees are
reasonable, equitable, and not unfairly
discriminatory.
B. Self-Regulatory Organization’s
Statement on Burden on Competition
The Exchange does not believe that
the proposed rule change will impose
any burden on competition that is not
necessary or appropriate in furtherance
of the purposes of the Act. An
exchange’s ability to price its
proprietary market data feed products is
constrained by actual competition for
the sale of proprietary market data
products, the joint product nature of
exchange platforms, and the existence of
alternatives to the Exchange’s
proprietary data.
The Existence of Actual Competition.
The market for proprietary data
products is currently competitive and
inherently contestable because there is
fierce competition for the inputs
necessary for the creation of proprietary
data and strict pricing discipline for the
proprietary products themselves.
Numerous exchanges compete with
each other for options trades and sales
of market data itself, providing ample
opportunities for entrepreneurs who
wish to compete in any or all of those
areas, including producing and
distributing their own options market
data. Proprietary options data products
are produced and distributed by each
individual exchange, as well as other
entities, in a vigorously competitive
market. Indeed, the U.S. Department of
Justice (‘‘DOJ’’) (the primary antitrust
regulator) has expressly acknowledged
the aggressive actual competition among
exchanges, including for the sale of
proprietary market data. In 2011, the
DOJ stated that exchanges ‘‘compete
head to head to offer real-time equity
data products. These data products
include the best bid and offer of every
exchange and information on each
equity trade, including the last sale.’’ 16
Similarly, the options markets
Commission’s 2000 Concept Release on the
Regulation of Market Information Fees and
Revenues, which can be found on the Commission’s
Web site at https://www.sec.gov/rules/concept/
s72899/buck1.htm.
16 Press Release, U.S. Department of Justice,
Assistant Attorney General Christine Varney Holds
Conference Call Regarding NASDAQ OMX Group
Inc. and IntercontinentalExchange Inc. Abandoning
Their Bid for NYSE Euronext (May 16, 2011),
available at https://www.justice.gov/iso/opa/atr/
speeches/2011/at-speech-110516.html; see also
Complaint in U.S. v. Deutsche Borse AG and NYSE
Euronext, Case No. 11–cv–2280 (D.C. Dist.) ¶ 24
(‘‘NYSE and Direct Edge compete head-to-head . . .
in the provision of real-time proprietary equity data
products.’’).
E:\FR\FM\20JAN1.SGM
20JAN1
Federal Register / Vol. 81, No. 12 / Wednesday, January 20, 2016 / Notices
tkelley on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
vigorously compete with respect to
options data products.17
Moreover, competitive markets for
order flow, executions, and transaction
reports provide pricing discipline for
the inputs of proprietary options data
products and therefore constrain
markets from overpricing proprietary
options market data. Broker-dealers
send their order flow to multiple
venues, rather than providing them all
to a single venue, which in turn
reinforces this competitive constraint.
Options markets, similar to the equities
markets, are highly fragmented.18
If an exchange succeeds in competing
for quotations, order flow, and trade
executions, then it earns trading
revenues and increases the value of its
proprietary options market data
products because they will contain
greater quote and trade information.
Conversely, if an exchange is less
successful in attracting quotes, order
flow, and trade executions, then its
options market data products may be
less desirable to customers using them
in support of order routing and trading
decisions in light of the diminished
content; options data products offered
by competing venues may become
correspondingly more attractive. Thus,
competition for quotations, order flow,
and trade executions puts significant
pressure on an exchange to maintain
both execution and data fees at
reasonable levels.
In addition, in the case of products
that are also redistributed through
market data vendors, such as Bloomberg
and Thompson Reuters, the vendors
themselves provide additional price
discipline for proprietary data products
because they control the primary means
of access to certain end users. These
vendors impose price discipline based
upon their business models. For
example, vendors that assess a
surcharge on data they sell are able to
refuse to offer proprietary products that
their end users do not or will not
purchase in sufficient numbers. Vendors
will not elect to make available NYSE
Amex Options Product unless their
customers request it, and customers will
not elect to pay the proposed fees unless
NYSE Amex Options Product can
provide value by sufficiently increasing
17 See, e.g., Securities Exchange Act Release No.
67466 (July 19, 2012), 77 FR 43629 (July 25, 2012)
(SR–Phlx–2012–93), which describes a variety of
options market data products and their pricing.
18 See, e.g., Press Release, TABB Says US Equity
Options Market Makers Need Scalable Technology
to Compete in Today’s Complex Market Structure
(February 25, 2013), available at https://www.
tabbgroup.com/PageDetail.aspx?PageID=16&
ItemID=1231; Fragmentation Vexes Options
Markets (April 21, 2014), available at https://market
smedia.com/fragmentation-vexes-options-market/.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:12 Jan 19, 2016
Jkt 238001
revenues or reducing costs in the
customer’s business in a manner that
will offset the fees. All of these factors
operate as constraints on pricing
proprietary data products.
Joint Product Nature of Exchange
Platform
Transaction execution and proprietary
data products are complementary in that
market data is both an input and a
byproduct of the execution service. In
fact, proprietary market data and trade
executions are a paradigmatic example
of joint products with joint costs. The
decision of whether and on which
platform to post an order will depend
on the attributes of the platforms where
the order can be posted, including the
execution fees, data availability and
quality, and price and distribution of
data products. Without a platform to
post quotations, receive orders, and
execute trades, exchange data products
would not exist.
The costs of producing market data
include not only the costs of the data
distribution infrastructure, but also the
costs of designing, maintaining, and
operating the exchange’s platform for
posting quotes, accepting orders, and
executing transactions and the cost of
regulating the exchange to ensure its fair
operation and maintain investor
confidence. The total return that a
trading platform earns reflects the
revenues it receives from both products
and the joint costs it incurs.
Moreover, an exchange’s brokerdealer customers generally view the
costs of transaction executions and
market data as a unified cost of doing
business with the exchange. A brokerdealer will only choose to direct orders
to an exchange if the revenue from the
transaction exceeds its cost, including
the cost of any market data that the
broker-dealer chooses to buy in support
of its order routing and trading
decisions. If the costs of the transaction
are not offset by its value, then the
broker-dealer may choose instead not to
purchase the product and trade away
from that exchange. There is substantial
evidence of the strong correlation
between order flow and market data
purchases. For example, in September
2015, more than 80% of the transaction
volume on each of NYSE MKT and
NYSE MKT’s affiliates New York Stock
Exchange LLC (‘‘NYSE’’) and NYSE
Arca, Inc. (‘‘NYSE Arca’’) was executed
by market participants that purchased
one or more proprietary market data
products (the 20 firms were not the
same for each market). A supracompetitive increase in the fees for
either executions or market data would
PO 00000
Frm 00134
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
3227
create a risk of reducing an exchange’s
revenues from both products.
Other market participants have noted
that proprietary market data and trade
executions are joint products of a joint
platform and have common costs.19 The
Exchange agrees with and adopts those
discussions and the arguments therein.
The Exchange also notes that the
economics literature confirms that there
is no way to allocate common costs
between joint products that would shed
any light on competitive or efficient
pricing.20
Analyzing the cost of market data
product production and distribution in
isolation from the cost of all of the
inputs supporting the creation of market
data and market data products will
inevitably underestimate the cost of the
data and data products because it is
impossible to obtain the data inputs to
create market data products without a
fast, technologically robust, and wellregulated execution system, and system
and regulatory costs affect the price of
both obtaining the market data itself and
creating and distributing market data
products. It would be equally
misleading, however, to attribute all of
an exchange’s costs to the market data
portion of an exchange’s joint products.
Rather, all of an exchange’s costs are
incurred for the unified purposes of
attracting order flow, executing and/or
routing orders, and generating and
selling data about market activity. The
19 See Securities Exchange Act Release No. 72153
(May 12, 2014), 79 FR 28575, 28578 n.15 (May 16,
2014) (SR–NASDAQ–2014–045) (‘‘[A]ll of the
exchange’s costs are incurred for the unified
purposes of attracting order flow, executing and/or
routing orders, and generating and selling data
about market activity. The total return that an
exchange earns reflects the revenues it receives
from the joint products and the total costs of the
joint products.’’). See also Securities Exchange Act
Release No. 62907 (Sept. 14, 2010), 75 FR 57314,
57317 (Sept. 20, 2010) (SR–NASDAQ–2010–110),
and Securities Exchange Act Release No. 62908
(Sept. 14, 2010), 75 FR 57321, 57324 (Sept. 20,
2010) (SR–NASDAQ–2010–111).
20 See generally Mark Hirschey, ‘‘Fundamentals of
Managerial Economics,’’ at 600 (2009) (‘‘It is
important to note, however, that although it is
possible to determine the separate marginal costs of
goods produced in variable proportions, it is
impossible to determine their individual average
costs. This is because common costs are expenses
necessary for manufacture of a joint product.
Common costs of production—raw material and
equipment costs, management expenses, and other
overhead—cannot be allocated to each individual
by-product on any economically sound basis. . . .
Any allocation of common costs is wrong and
arbitrary.’’). This is not new economic theory. See,
e.g., F.W. Taussig, ‘‘A Contribution to the Theory
of Railway Rates,’’ Quarterly Journal of Economics
V(4) 438, 465 (July 1891) (‘‘Yet, surely, the division
is purely arbitrary. These items of cost, in fact, are
jointly incurred for both sorts of traffic; and I cannot
share the hope entertained by the statistician of the
Commission, Professor Henry C. Adams, that we
shall ever reach a mode of apportionment that will
lead to trustworthy results.’’).
E:\FR\FM\20JAN1.SGM
20JAN1
3228
Federal Register / Vol. 81, No. 12 / Wednesday, January 20, 2016 / Notices
tkelley on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
total return that an exchange earns
reflects the revenues it receives from the
joint products and the total costs of the
joint products.
As noted above, the level of
competition and contestability in the
market is evident in the numerous
alternative venues that compete for
order flow, including 13 options selfregulatory organization (‘‘SRO’’)
markets. Three of the 13 have launched
operations since December 2012.21 The
Exchange believes that these new
entrants demonstrate that competition is
robust.
Competition among trading platforms
can be expected to constrain the
aggregate return that each platform
earns from the sale of its joint products,
but different trading platforms may
choose from a range of possible, and
equally reasonable, pricing strategies as
the means of recovering total costs. For
example, some platforms may choose to
pay rebates to attract orders, charge
relatively low prices for market data
products (or provide market data
products free of charge), and charge
relatively high prices for accessing
posted liquidity. Other platforms may
choose a strategy of paying lower
rebates (or no rebates) to attract orders,
setting relatively high prices for market
data products, and setting relatively low
prices for accessing posted liquidity. For
example, BATS Global Markets
(‘‘BATS’’) and Direct Edge, which
previously operated as ATSs and
obtained exchange status in 2008 and
2010, respectively, provided certain
market data at no charge on their Web
sites in order to attract more order flow,
and used revenue rebates from resulting
additional executions to maintain low
execution charges for their users.22 In
this environment, there is no economic
basis for regulating maximum prices for
one of the joint products in an industry
in which suppliers face competitive
constraints with regard to the joint
offering.
21 See Securities Exchange Act Release Nos.
70050 (July 26, 2013), 78 FR 46622 (August 1, 2013)
(approving exchange registration for Topaz
Exchange, LLC) (known as ISE Gemini); 68341
(December 3, 2012), 77 FR 73065 (December 7,
2012) (approving exchange registration for Miami
International Securities Exchange LLC (‘‘Miami
Exchange’’)); and 75650 (August 7, 2015), 80 FR
48600 (August 13, 2015) (establishing rules
governing the trading of options on the EDGX
options market).
22 This is simply a securities market-specific
example of the well-established principle that in
certain circumstances more sales at lower margins
can be more profitable than fewer sales at higher
margins; this example is additional evidence that
market data is an inherent part of a market’s joint
platform.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:12 Jan 19, 2016
Jkt 238001
Existence of Alternatives
The large number of SROs that
currently produce proprietary data or
are currently capable of producing it
provides further pricing discipline for
proprietary data products. Each SRO is
currently permitted to produce and sell
proprietary data products, and many
currently do, including but not limited
to the Exchange, NYSE Arca, CBOE, C2
Options Exchange, Inc., ISE, ISE
Gemini, NASDAQ, PHLX, BX, BATS
and Miami Exchange.
The fact that proprietary data from
vendors can bypass SROs is significant
in two respects. First, non-SROs can
compete directly with SROs for the
production and sale of proprietary data
products. By way of example, BATS and
NYSE Arca both published proprietary
data on the Internet before registering as
exchanges. Second, because a single
order or transaction report can appear in
an SRO proprietary product, a non-SRO
proprietary product, or both, the amount
of data available via proprietary
products is greater in size than the
actual number of orders and transaction
reports that exist in the marketplace.
Because market data users can find
suitable substitutes for most proprietary
market data products, a market that
overprices its market data products
stands a high risk that users may
substitute another source of market data
information for its own.
In addition to the competition and
price discipline described above, the
market for proprietary data products is
also highly contestable because market
entry is rapid and inexpensive. The
history of electronic trading is replete
with examples of entrants that swiftly
grew into some of the largest electronic
trading platforms and proprietary data
producers: Archipelago, Bloomberg
Tradebook, Island, RediBook, Attain,
TrackECN, BATS and Direct Edge. As
noted above, BATS launched as an ATS
in 2006 and became an exchange in
2008, while Direct Edge began
operations in 2007 and obtained
exchange status in 2010. As noted
above, three new options exchanges
have launched operations since
December 2012.23
In determining the proposed fees, the
Exchange considered the
competitiveness of the market for
proprietary options data and all of the
implications of that competition. The
Exchange believes that it has considered
all relevant factors and has not
considered irrelevant factors in order to
establish fair, reasonable, and not
unreasonably discriminatory fees and an
equitable allocation of fees among all
users. The existence of numerous
alternatives to the Exchange’s products,
including proprietary data from other
sources, ensures that the Exchange
cannot set unreasonable fees, or fees
that are unreasonably discriminatory,
when vendors and subscribers can elect
these alternatives or choose not to
purchase a specific proprietary data
product if the attendant fees are not
justified by the returns that any
particular vendor or data recipient
would achieve through the purchase.
C. Self-Regulatory Organization’s
Statement on Comments on the
Proposed Rule Change Received From
Members, Participants, or Others
No written comments were solicited
or received with respect to the proposed
rule change.
III. Date of Effectiveness of the
Proposed Rule Change and Timing for
Commission Action
The foregoing rule change is effective
upon filing pursuant to section
19(b)(3)(A) 24 of the Act and
subparagraph (f)(2) of Rule 19b–4 25
thereunder, because it establishes a due,
fee, or other charge imposed by the
Exchange.
At any time within 60 days of the
filing of such proposed rule change, the
Commission summarily may
temporarily suspend such rule change if
it appears to the Commission that such
action is necessary or appropriate in the
public interest, for the protection of
investors, or otherwise in furtherance of
the purposes of the Act. If the
Commission takes such action, the
Commission shall institute proceedings
under section 19(b)(2)(B) 26 of the Act to
determine whether the proposed rule
change should be approved or
disapproved.
IV. Solicitation of Comments
Interested persons are invited to
submit written data, views, and
arguments concerning the foregoing,
including whether the proposed rule
change is consistent with the Act.
Comments may be submitted by any of
the following methods:
Electronic Comments
• Use the Commission’s Internet
comment form (https://www.sec.gov/
rules/sro.shtml); or
• Send an email to rule-comments@
sec.gov. Please include File No. SR–
NYSEMKT–2015–113 on the subject
line.
24 15
U.S.C. 78s(b)(3)(A).
CFR 240.19b–4(f)(2).
26 15 U.S.C. 78s(b)(2)(B).
25 17
23 See
PO 00000
supra note 21.
Frm 00135
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
E:\FR\FM\20JAN1.SGM
20JAN1
Federal Register / Vol. 81, No. 12 / Wednesday, January 20, 2016 / Notices
Paper Comments
• Send paper comments in triplicate
to Secretary, Securities and Exchange
Commission, 100 F Street NE.,
Washington, DC 20549–1090.
All submissions should refer to File No.
SR–NYSEMKT–2015–113. This file
number should be included on the
subject line if email is used. To help the
Commission process and review your
comments more efficiently, please use
only one method. The Commission will
post all comments on the Commission’s
Internet Web site (https://www.sec.gov/
rules/sro.shtml). Copies of the
submission, all subsequent
amendments, all written statements
with respect to the proposed rule
change that are filed with the
Commission, and all written
communications relating to the
proposed rule change between the
Commission and any person, other than
those that may be withheld from the
public in accordance with the
provisions of 5 U.S.C. 552, will be
available for Web site viewing and
printing in the Commission’s Public
Reference Room, 100 F Street NE.,
Washington, DC 20549 on official
business days between the hours of
10:00 a.m. and 3:00 p.m. Copies of such
filing also will be available for
inspection and copying at the principal
office of the Exchange. All comments
received will be posted without change;
the Commission does not edit personal
identifying information from
submissions. You should submit only
information that you wish to make
available publicly. All submissions
should refer to File No. SR–NYSEMKT–
2015–113, and should be submitted on
or before February 10, 2016.
For the Commission, by the Division of
Trading and Markets, pursuant to delegated
authority.27
Robert W. Errett,
Deputy Secretary.
[FR Doc. 2016–00900 Filed 1–19–16; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 8011–01–P
SMALL BUSINESS ADMINISTRATION
[Disaster Declaration #14593 and #14594]
Kansas Disaster #KS–00095
U.S. Small Business
Administration.
ACTION: Notice.
tkelley on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
AGENCY:
This is a notice of an
Administrative declaration of a disaster
for the State of Kansas dated 1/11/2016.
Incident: Flooding.
SUMMARY:
27 17
CFR 200.30–3(a)(12).
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:12 Jan 19, 2016
Jkt 238001
Incident Period: 12/26/2015 through
12/29/2015.
Effective Date: 1/11/2016.
Physical Loan Application Deadline
Date: 3/11/2016.
Economic Injury (EIDL) Loan
Application Deadline Date: 10/11/2016.
ADDRESSES: Submit completed loan
applications to: U.S. Small Business
Administration, Processing And
Disbursement Center, 14925 Kingsport
Road, Fort Worth, TX 76155.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: A.
Escobar, Office of Disaster Assistance,
U.S. Small Business Administration,
409 3rd Street SW., Suite 6050,
Washington, DC 20416.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: Notice is
hereby given that as a result of the
Administrator’s disaster declaration,
applications for disaster loans may be
filed at the address listed above or other
locally announced locations.
The following areas have been
determined to be adversely affected by
the disaster:
Primary Counties: Cherokee.
Contiguous Counties:
Kansas: Crawford, Labette.
Missouri: Jasper, Newton.
Oklahoma: Craig, Ottawa.
The Interest Rates are:
3229
DEPARTMENT OF STATE
[Public Notice: 9408]
U.S. Department of State Advisory
Committee on Private International
Law (ACPIL): Public Meeting on Family
Law
The Office of the Assistant Legal
Adviser for Private International Law,
Department of State, gives notice of a
public meeting to discuss an upcoming
meeting at the Hague Conference on
Private International Law (‘‘Hague
Conference’’) on the topic of
international parentage and surrogacy.
The public meeting will take place on
Tuesday, February 9, 2016 from 1 p.m.
until 4 p.m. EST. This is not a meeting
of the full Advisory Committee.
In March 2015, the Council on
General Affairs and Policy of the Hague
Conference decided that an Experts’
Group should be convened to explore
the feasibility of advancing work on
private international law issues
surrounding the status of children,
including issues arising from
international surrogacy arrangements.
The first meeting of the Experts’ Group
will be held February 15–18, 2016, in
The Hague.
The purpose of the public meeting is
Percent
to obtain the views of concerned
stakeholders on matters that might be
For Physical Damage:
addressed at the upcoming Experts’
Homeowners With Credit Available Elsewhere ......................
3.625 Group meeting. Those who cannot
attend but wish to comment are
Homeowners Without Credit
Available Elsewhere ..............
1.813 welcome to do so by email to Michael
Businesses With Credit AvailCoffee at coffeems@state.gov.
able Elsewhere ......................
6.000
Time and Place: The meeting will take
Businesses
Without
Credit
place from 1 p.m. until 4 p.m. EST in
Available Elsewhere ..............
4.000
Room 9.04, State Department Annex 17,
Non-Profit Organizations With
Credit Available Elsewhere ...
2.625 600 19th Street NW., Washington, DC
20522. Participants should plan to
Non-Profit Organizations Witharrive at the North Entrance by 12:40
out Credit Available Elsewhere .....................................
2.625 p.m. for visitor screening. If you are
For Economic Injury:
unable to attend the public meeting and
Businesses & Small Agricultural
would like to participate from a remote
Cooperatives Without Credit
location, teleconferencing will be
Available Elsewhere ..............
4.000
available.
Non-Profit Organizations WithPublic Participation: This meeting is
out Credit Available Elsewhere .....................................
2.625 open to the public, subject to the
capacity of the meeting room. Access to
the building is strictly controlled. For
The number assigned to this disaster
pre-clearance purposes, those planning
for physical damage is 14593 6 and for
to attend should email pil@state.gov
economic injury is 14594 0.
providing full name, address, date of
The States which received an EIDL
birth, citizenship, driver’s license or
Declaration # are Kansas, Missouri,
passport number, and email address.
Oklahoma.
This information will greatly facilitate
(Catalog of Federal Domestic Assistance
entry into the building. A member of the
Numbers 59008)
public needing reasonable
Dated: January 11, 2016.
accommodation should email pil@
Maria Contreras-Sweet,
state.gov not later than February 2,
Administrator.
2016. Requests made after that date will
[FR Doc. 2016–00921 Filed 1–19–16; 8:45 am]
be considered, but might not be able to
BILLING CODE 8025–01–P
be fulfilled. If you would like to
PO 00000
Frm 00136
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
E:\FR\FM\20JAN1.SGM
20JAN1
Agencies
[Federal Register Volume 81, Number 12 (Wednesday, January 20, 2016)]
[Notices]
[Pages 3225-3229]
From the Federal Register Online via the Government Publishing Office [www.gpo.gov]
[FR Doc No: 2016-00900]
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
SECURITIES AND EXCHANGE COMMISSION
[Release No. 34-76889; File No. SR-NYSEMKT-2015-113]
Self-Regulatory Organizations; NYSE MKT LLC; Notice of Filing and
Immediate Effectiveness of Proposed Rule Change To Amend Market Data
Fees for the NYSE Amex Options Product
January 13, 2016.
Pursuant to section 19(b)(1) \1\ of the Securities Exchange Act of
1934 (the ``Act'') \2\ and Rule 19b-4 thereunder,\3\ notice is hereby
given that, on December 31, 2015, NYSE MKT LLC (the ``Exchange'' or
``NYSE MKT'') filed with the Securities and Exchange Commission (the
``Commission'') the proposed rule change as described in Items I, II,
and III below, which Items have been prepared by the self-regulatory
organization. The Commission is publishing this notice to solicit
comments on the proposed rule change from interested persons.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1\ 15 U.S.C. 78s(b)(1).
\2\ 15 U.S.C. 78a.
\3\ 17 CFR 240.19b-4.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
I. Self-Regulatory Organization's Statement of the Terms of the
Substance of the Proposed Rule Change
The Exchange proposes to amend the fees for NYSE Amex Options
Product,\4\ as set forth on the NYSE Amex Options Proprietary Market
Data Fee Schedule (``Fee Schedule''). The Exchange proposes to
establish a multiple data feed fee effective January 1, 2016. The text
of the proposed rule change is available on the Exchange's Web site at
www.nyse.com, at the principal office of the Exchange, and at the
Commission's Public Reference Room.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\4\ See Securities Exchange Act Release Nos. 76022 (Sept. 29,
2015), 80 FR 60201 (Oct. 5, 2015) (SR-NYSEMKT-2015-68) (Notice). The
single fee for the NYSE Amex Options Product set forth on the Fee
Schedule is comprised of three data feeds: Amex Options Top, Amex
Options Deep, and Amex Options Complex.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
II. Self-Regulatory Organization's Statement of the Purpose of, and
Statutory Basis for, the Proposed Rule Change
In its filing with the Commission, the self-regulatory organization
included statements concerning the purpose of, and basis for, the
proposed rule change and discussed any comments it received on the
proposed rule change. The text of those statements may be examined at
the places specified in Item IV below. The Exchange has prepared
summaries, set forth in sections A, B, and C below, of the most
significant parts of such statements.
A. Self-Regulatory Organization's Statement of the Purpose of, and
Statutory Basis for, the Proposed Rule Change
1. Purpose
The Exchange proposes to amend the fees for NYSE Amex Options
Product,\5\ as set forth on the NYSE Amex Options Proprietary Market
Data Fee Schedule (``Fee Schedule''). The Exchange proposes to
establish a multiple data feed fee effective January 1, 2016.
Specifically, the Exchange proposes to establish a new monthly fee, the
``Multiple Data Feed Fee,'' that would apply to data recipients that
take a data feed for NYSE Amex Options Product in more than two
locations. Data recipients taking NYSE Amex Options Product in more
than two locations would be charged $200 per additional location per
product per month. No new reporting would be required.\6\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\5\ See Securities Exchange Act Release Nos. 76022 (Sept. 29,
2015), 80 FR 60201 (Oct. 5, 2015) (SR-NYSEMKT-2015-68) (Notice). The
single fee for the NYSE Amex Options Product set forth on the Fee
Schedule is comprised of three data feeds: Amex Options Top, Amex
Options Deep, and Amex Options Complex.
\6\ Data vendors currently report a unique Vendor Account Number
for each location at which they provide a data feed to a data
recipient. The Exchange considers each Vendor Account Number a
location. For example, if a data recipient has five Vendor Account
Numbers, representing five locations, for the receipt of the NYSE
Amex Options Product, that data recipient will pay the Multiple Data
Feed fee with respect to three of the five locations, or $600.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
2. Statutory Basis
The Exchange believes that the proposed rule change is consistent
with the provisions of section 6 of the Act,\7\ in general, and
sections 6(b)(4) and 6(b)(5) of the Act,\8\ in particular, in that it
provides an equitable allocation of reasonable fees among users and
recipients of the data and is not designed to permit unfair
discrimination among customers, issuers, and brokers.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\7\ 15 U.S.C. 78f(b).
\8\ 15 U.S.C. 78f(b)(4), (5).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The fees are also equitable and not unfairly discriminatory because
they will apply to all data recipients that choose to subscribe to NYSE
Amex Options Product.
The Exchange believes that it is reasonable to require data
recipients to pay a modest additional fee taking a data feed for a
market data product in more than two locations, because such data
recipients can derive substantial value from being able to consume the
product in as many locations as they want. In addition, there are
administrative burdens associated with tracking each location at which
a data recipient receives the product. The Multiple Data Feed Fee is
designed to encourage data recipients to better manage their requests
for additional data feeds and to monitor their usage of data feeds. The
proposed fee is designed to apply to data feeds received in more than
two locations so that each data recipient can have one primary and one
backup data location before having to pay a multiple data feed fee. The
Exchange notes that this pricing is consistent with similar pricing
adopted in 2013 by the Consolidated Tape Association (``CTA'').\9\ The
Exchange also notes that the OPRA Plan imposes a similar charge of $100
per connection for circuit connections in addition to the primary and
backup connections.\10\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\9\ See Securities Exchange Act Release No. 70010 (July 19,
2013), 78 FR 44984 (July 25, 2013) (SR-CTA/CQ-2013-04).
\10\ See ``Direct Access Fee,'' Options Price Reporting
Authority Fee Schedule Fee Schedule PRA Plan at https://www.opradata.com/pdf/fee_schedule.pdf
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The Exchange notes that NYSE Amex Options Product is entirely
optional.
[[Page 3226]]
The Exchange is not required to make NYSE Amex Options Product
available or to offer any specific pricing alternatives to any
customers, nor is any firm required to purchase NYSE Amex Options
Product. Firms that do purchase NYSE Amex Options Product do so for the
primary goals of using it to increase revenues, reduce expenses, and in
some instances compete directly with the Exchange (including for order
flow); those firms are able to determine for themselves whether NYSE
Amex Options Product or any other similar products are attractively
priced or not.
Firms that do not wish to purchase NYSE Amex Options Product have a
variety of alternative market data products from which to choose,\11\
or if NYSE Amex Options Product does not provide sufficient value to
firms as offered based on the uses those firms have or planned to make
of it, such firms may simply choose to conduct their business
operations in ways that do not use NYSE Amex Options Product or use it
at different levels or in different configurations. The Exchange notes
that broker-dealers are not required to purchase proprietary market
data to comply with their best execution obligations.\12\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\11\ For example, Chicago Board Options Exchange (``CBOE'')
charges, for its ``Complex Order Book Feed,'' a Distributor Fee of
$3,000 per month, a Professional User Fee of $25 per month and a
Non-Professional User Fee of $1 per month. See the CBOE ``Complex
Order Book Feed'' product and pricing information, available at
https://www.cboe.org/MDX/CSM/OBOOKMain.aspx. NASDAQ OMX PHLX LLC
(``PHLX'') also offers a market data product entitled ``PHLX
Orders,'' which includes order and last sale information for complex
strategies and other market data, and charges a $3,000 internal
monthly fee ($3,500 for external), $2,000 per Distributor and $500
per subscriber. See PHLX ``PHLX Orders'' market data product and
pricing information, available at https://www.nasdaqtrader.com/Micro.aspx?id=PHLXOrders and https://www.nasdaqtrader.com/Trader.aspx?id=DPPriceListOptions#PHLX, respectively.
\12\ See FINRA Regulatory Notice 15-46, ``Best Execution,''
November 2015.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The decision of the United States Court of Appeals for the District
of Columbia Circuit in NetCoalition v. SEC, 615 F.3d 525 (D.C. Cir.
2010), upheld reliance by the Securities and Exchange Commission
(``Commission'') upon the existence of competitive market mechanisms to
set reasonable and equitably allocated fees for proprietary market
data:
In fact, the legislative history indicates that the Congress
intended that the market system `evolve through the interplay of
competitive forces as unnecessary regulatory restrictions are
removed' and that the SEC wield its regulatory power `in those
situations where competition may not be sufficient,' such as in the
creation of a `consolidated transactional reporting system.'
Id. at 535 (quoting H.R. Rep. No. 94-229 at 92 (1975), as reprinted in
1975 U.S.C.C.A.N. 323). The court agreed with the Commission's
conclusion that ``Congress intended that `competitive forces should
dictate the services and practices that constitute the U.S. national
market system for trading equity securities.' '' \13\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\13\ NetCoalition, 615 F.3d at 535.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
As explained below in the Exchange's Statement on Burden on
Competition, the Exchange believes that there is substantial evidence
of competition in the marketplace for proprietary market data and that
the Commission can rely upon such evidence in concluding that the fees
established in this filing are the product of competition and therefore
satisfy the relevant statutory standards.\14\ In addition, the
existence of alternatives to these data products, such as options data
from other sources, as described below, further ensures that the
Exchange cannot set unreasonable fees, or fees that are unreasonably
discriminatory, when vendors and subscribers can select such
alternatives.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\14\ Section 916 of the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and
Consumer Protection Act of 2010 (the ``Dodd-Frank Act'') amended
paragraph (A) of section 19(b)(3) of the Act, 15 U.S.C. 78s(b)(3),
to make clear that all exchange fees for market data may be filed by
exchanges on an immediately effective basis.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
As the NetCoalition decision noted, the Commission is not required
to undertake a cost-of-service or ratemaking approach. The Exchange
believes that, even if it were possible as a matter of economic theory,
cost-based pricing for proprietary market data would be so complicated
that it could not be done practically or offer any significant
benefits.\15\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\15\ The Exchange believes that cost-based pricing would be
impractical because it would create enormous administrative burdens
for all parties and the Commission to cost-regulate a large number
of participants and standardize and analyze extraordinary amounts of
information, accounts, and reports. In addition, and as described
below, it is impossible to regulate market data prices in isolation
from prices charged by markets for other services that are joint
products. Cost-based rate regulation would also lead to litigation
and may distort incentives, including those to minimize costs and to
innovate, leading to further waste. Under cost-based pricing, the
Commission would be burdened with determining a fair rate of return,
and the industry could experience frequent rate increases based on
escalating expense levels. Even in industries historically subject
to utility regulation, cost-based ratemaking has been discredited.
As such, the Exchange believes that cost-based ratemaking would be
inappropriate for proprietary market data and inconsistent with
Congress's direction that the Commission use its authority to foster
the development of the national market system, and that market
forces will continue to provide appropriate pricing discipline. See
Appendix C to NYSE's comments to the Commission's 2000 Concept
Release on the Regulation of Market Information Fees and Revenues,
which can be found on the Commission's Web site at https://www.sec.gov/rules/concept/s72899/buck1.htm.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
For these reasons, the Exchange believes that the proposed fees are
reasonable, equitable, and not unfairly discriminatory.
B. Self-Regulatory Organization's Statement on Burden on Competition
The Exchange does not believe that the proposed rule change will
impose any burden on competition that is not necessary or appropriate
in furtherance of the purposes of the Act. An exchange's ability to
price its proprietary market data feed products is constrained by
actual competition for the sale of proprietary market data products,
the joint product nature of exchange platforms, and the existence of
alternatives to the Exchange's proprietary data.
The Existence of Actual Competition.
The market for proprietary data products is currently competitive
and inherently contestable because there is fierce competition for the
inputs necessary for the creation of proprietary data and strict
pricing discipline for the proprietary products themselves. Numerous
exchanges compete with each other for options trades and sales of
market data itself, providing ample opportunities for entrepreneurs who
wish to compete in any or all of those areas, including producing and
distributing their own options market data. Proprietary options data
products are produced and distributed by each individual exchange, as
well as other entities, in a vigorously competitive market. Indeed, the
U.S. Department of Justice (``DOJ'') (the primary antitrust regulator)
has expressly acknowledged the aggressive actual competition among
exchanges, including for the sale of proprietary market data. In 2011,
the DOJ stated that exchanges ``compete head to head to offer real-time
equity data products. These data products include the best bid and
offer of every exchange and information on each equity trade, including
the last sale.'' \16\ Similarly, the options markets
[[Page 3227]]
vigorously compete with respect to options data products.\17\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\16\ Press Release, U.S. Department of Justice, Assistant
Attorney General Christine Varney Holds Conference Call Regarding
NASDAQ OMX Group Inc. and IntercontinentalExchange Inc. Abandoning
Their Bid for NYSE Euronext (May 16, 2011), available at https://www.justice.gov/iso/opa/atr/speeches/2011/at-speech-110516.html; see
also Complaint in U.S. v. Deutsche Borse AG and NYSE Euronext, Case
No. 11-cv-2280 (D.C. Dist.) ] 24 (``NYSE and Direct Edge compete
head-to-head . . . in the provision of real-time proprietary equity
data products.'').
\17\ See, e.g., Securities Exchange Act Release No. 67466 (July
19, 2012), 77 FR 43629 (July 25, 2012) (SR-Phlx-2012-93), which
describes a variety of options market data products and their
pricing.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Moreover, competitive markets for order flow, executions, and
transaction reports provide pricing discipline for the inputs of
proprietary options data products and therefore constrain markets from
overpricing proprietary options market data. Broker-dealers send their
order flow to multiple venues, rather than providing them all to a
single venue, which in turn reinforces this competitive constraint.
Options markets, similar to the equities markets, are highly
fragmented.\18\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\18\ See, e.g., Press Release, TABB Says US Equity Options
Market Makers Need Scalable Technology to Compete in Today's Complex
Market Structure (February 25, 2013), available at https://www.tabbgroup.com/PageDetail.aspx?PageID=16&ItemID=1231;
Fragmentation Vexes Options Markets (April 21, 2014), available at
https://marketsmedia.com/fragmentation-vexes-options-market/.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
If an exchange succeeds in competing for quotations, order flow,
and trade executions, then it earns trading revenues and increases the
value of its proprietary options market data products because they will
contain greater quote and trade information. Conversely, if an exchange
is less successful in attracting quotes, order flow, and trade
executions, then its options market data products may be less desirable
to customers using them in support of order routing and trading
decisions in light of the diminished content; options data products
offered by competing venues may become correspondingly more attractive.
Thus, competition for quotations, order flow, and trade executions puts
significant pressure on an exchange to maintain both execution and data
fees at reasonable levels.
In addition, in the case of products that are also redistributed
through market data vendors, such as Bloomberg and Thompson Reuters,
the vendors themselves provide additional price discipline for
proprietary data products because they control the primary means of
access to certain end users. These vendors impose price discipline
based upon their business models. For example, vendors that assess a
surcharge on data they sell are able to refuse to offer proprietary
products that their end users do not or will not purchase in sufficient
numbers. Vendors will not elect to make available NYSE Amex Options
Product unless their customers request it, and customers will not elect
to pay the proposed fees unless NYSE Amex Options Product can provide
value by sufficiently increasing revenues or reducing costs in the
customer's business in a manner that will offset the fees. All of these
factors operate as constraints on pricing proprietary data products.
Joint Product Nature of Exchange Platform
Transaction execution and proprietary data products are
complementary in that market data is both an input and a byproduct of
the execution service. In fact, proprietary market data and trade
executions are a paradigmatic example of joint products with joint
costs. The decision of whether and on which platform to post an order
will depend on the attributes of the platforms where the order can be
posted, including the execution fees, data availability and quality,
and price and distribution of data products. Without a platform to post
quotations, receive orders, and execute trades, exchange data products
would not exist.
The costs of producing market data include not only the costs of
the data distribution infrastructure, but also the costs of designing,
maintaining, and operating the exchange's platform for posting quotes,
accepting orders, and executing transactions and the cost of regulating
the exchange to ensure its fair operation and maintain investor
confidence. The total return that a trading platform earns reflects the
revenues it receives from both products and the joint costs it incurs.
Moreover, an exchange's broker-dealer customers generally view the
costs of transaction executions and market data as a unified cost of
doing business with the exchange. A broker-dealer will only choose to
direct orders to an exchange if the revenue from the transaction
exceeds its cost, including the cost of any market data that the
broker-dealer chooses to buy in support of its order routing and
trading decisions. If the costs of the transaction are not offset by
its value, then the broker-dealer may choose instead not to purchase
the product and trade away from that exchange. There is substantial
evidence of the strong correlation between order flow and market data
purchases. For example, in September 2015, more than 80% of the
transaction volume on each of NYSE MKT and NYSE MKT's affiliates New
York Stock Exchange LLC (``NYSE'') and NYSE Arca, Inc. (``NYSE Arca'')
was executed by market participants that purchased one or more
proprietary market data products (the 20 firms were not the same for
each market). A supra-competitive increase in the fees for either
executions or market data would create a risk of reducing an exchange's
revenues from both products.
Other market participants have noted that proprietary market data
and trade executions are joint products of a joint platform and have
common costs.\19\ The Exchange agrees with and adopts those discussions
and the arguments therein. The Exchange also notes that the economics
literature confirms that there is no way to allocate common costs
between joint products that would shed any light on competitive or
efficient pricing.\20\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\19\ See Securities Exchange Act Release No. 72153 (May 12,
2014), 79 FR 28575, 28578 n.15 (May 16, 2014) (SR-NASDAQ-2014-045)
(``[A]ll of the exchange's costs are incurred for the unified
purposes of attracting order flow, executing and/or routing orders,
and generating and selling data about market activity. The total
return that an exchange earns reflects the revenues it receives from
the joint products and the total costs of the joint products.'').
See also Securities Exchange Act Release No. 62907 (Sept. 14, 2010),
75 FR 57314, 57317 (Sept. 20, 2010) (SR-NASDAQ-2010-110), and
Securities Exchange Act Release No. 62908 (Sept. 14, 2010), 75 FR
57321, 57324 (Sept. 20, 2010) (SR-NASDAQ-2010-111).
\20\ See generally Mark Hirschey, ``Fundamentals of Managerial
Economics,'' at 600 (2009) (``It is important to note, however, that
although it is possible to determine the separate marginal costs of
goods produced in variable proportions, it is impossible to
determine their individual average costs. This is because common
costs are expenses necessary for manufacture of a joint product.
Common costs of production--raw material and equipment costs,
management expenses, and other overhead--cannot be allocated to each
individual by-product on any economically sound basis. . . . Any
allocation of common costs is wrong and arbitrary.''). This is not
new economic theory. See, e.g., F.W. Taussig, ``A Contribution to
the Theory of Railway Rates,'' Quarterly Journal of Economics V(4)
438, 465 (July 1891) (``Yet, surely, the division is purely
arbitrary. These items of cost, in fact, are jointly incurred for
both sorts of traffic; and I cannot share the hope entertained by
the statistician of the Commission, Professor Henry C. Adams, that
we shall ever reach a mode of apportionment that will lead to
trustworthy results.'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Analyzing the cost of market data product production and
distribution in isolation from the cost of all of the inputs supporting
the creation of market data and market data products will inevitably
underestimate the cost of the data and data products because it is
impossible to obtain the data inputs to create market data products
without a fast, technologically robust, and well-regulated execution
system, and system and regulatory costs affect the price of both
obtaining the market data itself and creating and distributing market
data products. It would be equally misleading, however, to attribute
all of an exchange's costs to the market data portion of an exchange's
joint products. Rather, all of an exchange's costs are incurred for the
unified purposes of attracting order flow, executing and/or routing
orders, and generating and selling data about market activity. The
[[Page 3228]]
total return that an exchange earns reflects the revenues it receives
from the joint products and the total costs of the joint products.
As noted above, the level of competition and contestability in the
market is evident in the numerous alternative venues that compete for
order flow, including 13 options self-regulatory organization (``SRO'')
markets. Three of the 13 have launched operations since December
2012.\21\ The Exchange believes that these new entrants demonstrate
that competition is robust.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\21\ See Securities Exchange Act Release Nos. 70050 (July 26,
2013), 78 FR 46622 (August 1, 2013) (approving exchange registration
for Topaz Exchange, LLC) (known as ISE Gemini); 68341 (December 3,
2012), 77 FR 73065 (December 7, 2012) (approving exchange
registration for Miami International Securities Exchange LLC
(``Miami Exchange'')); and 75650 (August 7, 2015), 80 FR 48600
(August 13, 2015) (establishing rules governing the trading of
options on the EDGX options market).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Competition among trading platforms can be expected to constrain
the aggregate return that each platform earns from the sale of its
joint products, but different trading platforms may choose from a range
of possible, and equally reasonable, pricing strategies as the means of
recovering total costs. For example, some platforms may choose to pay
rebates to attract orders, charge relatively low prices for market data
products (or provide market data products free of charge), and charge
relatively high prices for accessing posted liquidity. Other platforms
may choose a strategy of paying lower rebates (or no rebates) to
attract orders, setting relatively high prices for market data
products, and setting relatively low prices for accessing posted
liquidity. For example, BATS Global Markets (``BATS'') and Direct Edge,
which previously operated as ATSs and obtained exchange status in 2008
and 2010, respectively, provided certain market data at no charge on
their Web sites in order to attract more order flow, and used revenue
rebates from resulting additional executions to maintain low execution
charges for their users.\22\ In this environment, there is no economic
basis for regulating maximum prices for one of the joint products in an
industry in which suppliers face competitive constraints with regard to
the joint offering.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\22\ This is simply a securities market-specific example of the
well-established principle that in certain circumstances more sales
at lower margins can be more profitable than fewer sales at higher
margins; this example is additional evidence that market data is an
inherent part of a market's joint platform.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Existence of Alternatives
The large number of SROs that currently produce proprietary data or
are currently capable of producing it provides further pricing
discipline for proprietary data products. Each SRO is currently
permitted to produce and sell proprietary data products, and many
currently do, including but not limited to the Exchange, NYSE Arca,
CBOE, C2 Options Exchange, Inc., ISE, ISE Gemini, NASDAQ, PHLX, BX,
BATS and Miami Exchange.
The fact that proprietary data from vendors can bypass SROs is
significant in two respects. First, non-SROs can compete directly with
SROs for the production and sale of proprietary data products. By way
of example, BATS and NYSE Arca both published proprietary data on the
Internet before registering as exchanges. Second, because a single
order or transaction report can appear in an SRO proprietary product, a
non-SRO proprietary product, or both, the amount of data available via
proprietary products is greater in size than the actual number of
orders and transaction reports that exist in the marketplace. Because
market data users can find suitable substitutes for most proprietary
market data products, a market that overprices its market data products
stands a high risk that users may substitute another source of market
data information for its own.
In addition to the competition and price discipline described
above, the market for proprietary data products is also highly
contestable because market entry is rapid and inexpensive. The history
of electronic trading is replete with examples of entrants that swiftly
grew into some of the largest electronic trading platforms and
proprietary data producers: Archipelago, Bloomberg Tradebook, Island,
RediBook, Attain, TrackECN, BATS and Direct Edge. As noted above, BATS
launched as an ATS in 2006 and became an exchange in 2008, while Direct
Edge began operations in 2007 and obtained exchange status in 2010. As
noted above, three new options exchanges have launched operations since
December 2012.\23\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\23\ See supra note 21.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
In determining the proposed fees, the Exchange considered the
competitiveness of the market for proprietary options data and all of
the implications of that competition. The Exchange believes that it has
considered all relevant factors and has not considered irrelevant
factors in order to establish fair, reasonable, and not unreasonably
discriminatory fees and an equitable allocation of fees among all
users. The existence of numerous alternatives to the Exchange's
products, including proprietary data from other sources, ensures that
the Exchange cannot set unreasonable fees, or fees that are
unreasonably discriminatory, when vendors and subscribers can elect
these alternatives or choose not to purchase a specific proprietary
data product if the attendant fees are not justified by the returns
that any particular vendor or data recipient would achieve through the
purchase.
C. Self-Regulatory Organization's Statement on Comments on the Proposed
Rule Change Received From Members, Participants, or Others
No written comments were solicited or received with respect to the
proposed rule change.
III. Date of Effectiveness of the Proposed Rule Change and Timing for
Commission Action
The foregoing rule change is effective upon filing pursuant to
section 19(b)(3)(A) \24\ of the Act and subparagraph (f)(2) of Rule
19b-4 \25\ thereunder, because it establishes a due, fee, or other
charge imposed by the Exchange.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\24\ 15 U.S.C. 78s(b)(3)(A).
\25\ 17 CFR 240.19b-4(f)(2).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
At any time within 60 days of the filing of such proposed rule
change, the Commission summarily may temporarily suspend such rule
change if it appears to the Commission that such action is necessary or
appropriate in the public interest, for the protection of investors, or
otherwise in furtherance of the purposes of the Act. If the Commission
takes such action, the Commission shall institute proceedings under
section 19(b)(2)(B) \26\ of the Act to determine whether the proposed
rule change should be approved or disapproved.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\26\ 15 U.S.C. 78s(b)(2)(B).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
IV. Solicitation of Comments
Interested persons are invited to submit written data, views, and
arguments concerning the foregoing, including whether the proposed rule
change is consistent with the Act. Comments may be submitted by any of
the following methods:
Electronic Comments
Use the Commission's Internet comment form (https://www.sec.gov/rules/sro.shtml); or
Send an email to rule-comments@sec.gov. Please include
File No. SR-NYSEMKT-2015-113 on the subject line.
[[Page 3229]]
Paper Comments
Send paper comments in triplicate to Secretary, Securities
and Exchange Commission, 100 F Street NE., Washington, DC 20549-1090.
All submissions should refer to File No. SR-NYSEMKT-2015-113. This file
number should be included on the subject line if email is used. To help
the Commission process and review your comments more efficiently,
please use only one method. The Commission will post all comments on
the Commission's Internet Web site (https://www.sec.gov/rules/sro.shtml). Copies of the submission, all subsequent amendments, all
written statements with respect to the proposed rule change that are
filed with the Commission, and all written communications relating to
the proposed rule change between the Commission and any person, other
than those that may be withheld from the public in accordance with the
provisions of 5 U.S.C. 552, will be available for Web site viewing and
printing in the Commission's Public Reference Room, 100 F Street NE.,
Washington, DC 20549 on official business days between the hours of
10:00 a.m. and 3:00 p.m. Copies of such filing also will be available
for inspection and copying at the principal office of the Exchange. All
comments received will be posted without change; the Commission does
not edit personal identifying information from submissions. You should
submit only information that you wish to make available publicly. All
submissions should refer to File No. SR-NYSEMKT-2015-113, and should be
submitted on or before February 10, 2016.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\27\ 17 CFR 200.30-3(a)(12).
For the Commission, by the Division of Trading and Markets,
pursuant to delegated authority.\27\
Robert W. Errett,
Deputy Secretary.
[FR Doc. 2016-00900 Filed 1-19-16; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 8011-01-P