Self-Regulatory Organizations; NASDAQ OMX BX, Inc.; Notice of Filing and Immediate Effectiveness of Proposed Rule Change To Modify the Fees for Managed Data Solutions, 555-559 [2015-33209]
Download as PDF
555
Federal Register / Vol. 81, No. 3 / Wednesday, January 6, 2016 / Notices
comply with the Act’s requirements.
These programs differ from investment
companies because, among other things,
they provide individualized investment
advice to the client. The rule’s
provisions have the effect of ensuring
that clients in a program relying on the
rule receive advice tailored to the
client’s needs.
For a program to be eligible for the
rule’s safe harbor, each client’s account
must be managed on the basis of the
client’s financial situation and
investment objectives and in accordance
with any reasonable restrictions the
client imposes on managing the
account. When an account is opened,
the sponsor (or its designee) must obtain
information from each client regarding
the client’s financial situation and
investment objectives, and must allow
the client an opportunity to impose
reasonable restrictions on managing the
account. In addition, the sponsor (or its
designee) must contact the client
annually to determine whether the
client’s financial situation or investment
objectives have changed and whether
the client wishes to impose any
reasonable restrictions on the
management of the account or
reasonably modify existing restrictions.
The sponsor (or its designee) must also
notify the client quarterly, in writing, to
contact the sponsor (or its designee)
regarding changes to the client’s
financial situation, investment
objectives, or restrictions on the
account’s management.
Additionally, the sponsor (or its
designee) must provide each client with
a quarterly statement describing all
activity in the client’s account during
the previous quarter. The sponsor and
personnel of the client’s account
manager who know about the client’s
account and its management must be
reasonably available to consult with the
client. Each client also must retain
certain indicia of ownership of all
securities and funds in the account.
The Commission staff estimates that
16,537,781 clients participate each year
in investment advisory programs relying
on rule 3a–4. Of that number, the staff
estimates that 4,918,064 are new clients
and 11,619,717 are continuing clients.
The staff estimates that each year the
investment advisory program sponsors’
staff engage in 1.5 hours per new client
and 1 hour per continuing client to
prepare, conduct and/or review
interviews regarding the client’s
financial situation and investment
objectives as required by the rule.
Furthermore, the staff estimates that
each year the investment advisory
program sponsors’ staff spends 1 hour
per client to prepare and mail quarterly
client account statements, including
notices to update information. Based on
the estimates above, the Commission
estimates that the total annual burden of
the rule’s paperwork requirements is
35,534,594 hours.
The estimate of average burden hours
is made solely for the purposes of the
Paperwork Reduction Act. The estimate
is not derived from a comprehensive or
even a representative survey or study of
the costs of Commission rules and
forms. An agency may not conduct or
sponsor, and a person is not required to
respond to, a collection of information
unless it displays a currently valid OMB
control number.
The public may view the background
documentation for this information
collection at the following Web site,
www.reginfo.gov. Comments should be
directed to: (i) Desk Officer for the
Securities and Exchange Commission,
Office of Information and Regulatory
Affairs, Office of Management and
Budget, Room 10102, New Executive
Office Building, Washington, DC 20503,
or by sending an email to: Shagufta_
Ahmed@omb.eop.gov; and (ii) Pamela
Dyson, Director/Chief Information
Officer, Securities and Exchange
Commission, c/o Remi Pavlik-Simon,
100 F Street NE., Washington, DC 20549
or send an email to: PRA_Mailbox@
sec.gov. Comments must be submitted to
OMB within 30 days of this notice.
Dated: December 30, 2015.
Jill M. Peterson,
Assistant Secretary.
[FR Doc. 2015–33212 Filed 1–5–16; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 8011–01–P
SECURITIES AND EXCHANGE
COMMISSION
[Release No. 34–76796; File No. SR–BX–
2015–084)]
Self-Regulatory Organizations;
NASDAQ OMX BX, Inc.; Notice of Filing
and Immediate Effectiveness of
Proposed Rule Change To Modify the
Fees for Managed Data Solutions
December 30, 2015.
Pursuant to section 19(b)(1) of the
Securities Exchange Act of 1934
(‘‘Act’’),1 and Rule 19b–4 thereunder,2
notice is hereby given that on December
18, 2015, The NASDAQ OMX BX, Inc
(‘‘BX’’) filed with the Securities and
Exchange Commission (‘‘Commission’’)
the proposed rule change as described
in Items I, II, and III below, which Items
have been prepared by BX. The
Commission is publishing this notice to
solicit comments on the proposed rule
change from interested persons.
I. Self-Regulatory Organization’s
Statement of the Terms of the Substance
of the Proposed Rule Change
BX proposes to modify the charges to
be paid for Managed Data Solutions
(‘‘MDS’’). While the changes proposed
herein are effective upon filing, the
Exchange has designated that the
amendments be operative on January 1,
2016.
The text of the proposed rule change
is below. Proposed new language is
italicized; proposed deletions are
bracketed.
Rules of NASDAQ OMX BX
Equity Rules
*
*
*
*
*
7026. Distribution Models
(a) Managed Data Solutions.
Distributors and Subscribers of
Managed Data Solutions products
containing BX TotalView data (nondisplay use only) shall pay the
following fees:
FEE SCHEDULE FOR MANAGED DATA
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
Solutions
Price
Managed Data Solutions Administration Fee (for the right to offer Managed Data Solutions to client organizations).
BX Depth Data Professional Managed Data Solutions Subscriber Fee (Internal Use Only and includes BX
TotalView).
BX Depth Data Managed Data Solutions Non-Professional Subscriber Fee (Internal Use Only and includes
BX TotalView).
1 15
U.S.C. 78s(b)(1).
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:32 Jan 05, 2016
2 17
Jkt 238001
PO 00000
$[750]1,500/mo Per Distributor.
$1[0]50/mo Per Subscriber.
$20/mo Per Subscriber.
CFR 240.19b–4.
Frm 00097
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
E:\FR\FM\06JAN1.SGM
06JAN1
556
*
Federal Register / Vol. 81, No. 3 / Wednesday, January 6, 2016 / Notices
(b) No change.
*
*
*
*
II. Self-Regulatory Organization’s
Statement of the Purpose of, and
Statutory Basis for, the Proposed Rule
Change
In its filing with the Commission, BX
included statements concerning the
purpose of and basis for the proposed
rule change and discussed any
comments it received on the proposed
rule change. The text of these statements
may be examined at the places specified
in Item IV below. BX has prepared
summaries, set forth in Sections A, B,
and C below, of the most significant
aspects of such statements.
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
A. Self-Regulatory Organization’s
Statement of the Purpose of, and
Statutory Basis for, the Proposed Rule
Change
1. Purpose
The purpose of the proposed rule
change is to increase the charges to be
paid by distributors and subscribers of
Managed Data Solutions products
containing BX TotalView data (nondisplay use only). Specifically, the
Exchange proposes to increase the fee
charged to distributors for the right to
offer Managed Data Solutions to client
organizations to $1,500 per month per
distributor (‘‘MDS Administration
Fee’’), and the fee charged to
professional subscribers to $150 per
month per subscriber (‘‘MDS Subscriber
Fee’’). This proposed rule change will
not affect the pricing for nonprofessional subscribers.
MDS is a data delivery option
available to distributors of BX
TotalView. Under the MDS fee
structure, distributors may provide data
feeds, Application Programming
Interfaces (APIs) or similar automated
delivery solutions to client
organizations with only limited
entitlement controls. Through this
program, BX offers a much simpler
administration process for MDS
distributors and subscribers, reducing
the burden and cost of administration.
Subscribers of MDS may use the
information for internal purposes only
and may not distribute the information
outside of their organization. MDS
presents opportunities for small and
mid-size firms to achieve significant
cost savings over the cost of data feeds.
Both the MDS Administration Fee and
MDS Subscriber Fee have not changed
since their introduction in 2013.
Nevertheless, both distributors and
subscribers reap the benefits of BX’s
constant focus on the performance and
enhancements to these offerings. As
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:32 Jan 05, 2016
Jkt 238001
such, BX recently completed a
technology refresh to ensure that its data
feeds continue to achieve a high level of
performance and resiliency. The
Exchange has also upgraded and
refreshed its disaster recovery
capabilities, adding to the increased
focus on redundancy and resiliency.
2. Statutory Basis
The Exchange believes that the
proposed rule change is consistent with
the provisions of section 6 of the Act,3
in general, and with sections 6(b)(4) and
6(b)(5) of the Act,4 in particular, in that
it provides an equitable allocation of
reasonable fees among Subscribers and
recipients of BX data and is not
designed to permit unfair
discrimination between them. BX’s
proposal to increase the MDS
Administration Fee and MDS Subscriber
Fee is also consistent with the Act in
that it reflects an equitable allocation of
reasonable fees. The Commission has
long recognized the fair and equitable
and not unreasonably discriminatory
nature of assessing different fees for
distributors and professional and nonprofessional users of the same data. BX
also believes it is equitable to assess a
higher fee per professional user than to
an ordinary non-professional user due
to the enhanced flexibility, lower
overall costs and value that it offers
distributors.
In adopting Regulation NMS, the
Commission granted self-regulatory
organizations and broker-dealers
increased authority and flexibility to
offer new and unique market data to the
public.
The Commission concluded that
Regulation NMS—by deregulating the
market in proprietary data—would itself
further the Act’s goals of facilitating
efficiency and competition:
[E]fficiency is promoted when brokerdealers who do not need the data beyond the
prices, sizes, market center identifications of
the NBBO and consolidated last sale
information are not required to receive (and
pay for) such data. The Commission also
believes that efficiency is promoted when
broker-dealers may choose to receive (and
pay for) additional market data based on their
own internal analysis of the need for such
data.5
By removing ‘‘unnecessary regulatory
restrictions’’ on the ability of exchanges
to sell their own data, Regulation NMS
advanced the goals of the Act and the
principles reflected in its legislative
history. If the free market should
determine whether proprietary data is
3 15
U.S.C. 78f.
U.S.C. 78f(b)(4) and (5).
5 See Securities Exchange Act Release No. 51808
(June 9, 2005), 70 FR 37496 (June 29, 2005).
4 15
PO 00000
Frm 00098
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
sold to broker-dealers at all, it follows
that the price at which such data is sold
should be set by the market as well. BX
TotalView is precisely the sort of market
data products that the Commission
envisioned when it adopted Regulation
NMS.
The decision of the United States
Court of Appeals for the District of
Columbia Circuit in NetCoalition v.
SEC, 615 F.3d 525 (D.C. Cir. 2010)
(‘‘NetCoalition I’’), upheld the
Commission’s reliance upon
competitive markets to set reasonable
and equitably allocated fees for market
data. ‘‘In fact, the legislative history
indicates that the Congress intended
that the market system ‘evolve through
the interplay of competitive forces as
unnecessary regulatory restrictions are
removed’ and that the SEC wield its
regulatory power ‘in those situations
where competition may not be
sufficient,’ such as in the creation of a
‘consolidated transactional reporting
system.’ NetCoalition I, at 535 (quoting
H.R. Rep. No. 94–229, at 92 (1975), as
reprinted in 1975 U.S.C.C.A.N. 321,
323). The court agreed with the
Commission’s conclusion that
‘‘Congress intended that ‘competitive
forces should dictate the services and
practices that constitute the U.S.
national market system for trading
equity securities.’ ’’ 6
The Court in NetCoalition I, while
upholding the Commission’s conclusion
that competitive forces may be relied
upon to establish the fairness of prices,
nevertheless concluded that the record
in that case did not adequately support
the Commission’s conclusions as to the
competitive nature of the market for
NYSE Arca’s data product at issue in
that case. As explained below in BX’s
Statement on Burden on Competition,
however, BX believes that there is
substantial evidence of competition in
the marketplace for data that was not in
the record in the NetCoalition I case,
and that the Commission is entitled to
rely upon such evidence in concluding
fees are the product of competition, and
therefore in accordance with the
relevant statutory standards.7
Accordingly, any findings of the court
with respect to that product may not be
6 NetCoalition
I, at 535.
should also be noted that section 916 of the
Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer
Protection Act of 2010 (‘‘Dodd-Frank Act’’) has
amended paragraph (A) of section 19(b)(3) of the
Act, 15 U.S.C. 78s(b)(3), to make it clear that all
exchange fees, including fees for market data, may
be filed by exchanges on an immediately effective
basis. See also NetCoalition v. SEC, 715 F.3d 342
(D.C. Cir. 2013) (‘‘NetCoalition II’’) (finding no
jurisdiction to review Commission’s nonsuspension of immediately effective fee changes).
7 It
E:\FR\FM\06JAN1.SGM
06JAN1
Federal Register / Vol. 81, No. 3 / Wednesday, January 6, 2016 / Notices
relevant to the product at issue in this
filing.
BX believes that the allocation of the
proposed fee is fair and equitable in
accordance with section 6(b)(4) of the
Act, and not unreasonably
discriminatory in accordance with
section 6(b)(5) of the Act. As described
above, the proposed fee is based on
pricing conventions and distinctions
that exist in BX’s current fee schedule.
These distinctions are each based on
principles of fairness and equity that
have helped for many years to maintain
fair, equitable, and not unreasonably
discriminatory fees, and that apply with
equal or greater force to the current
proposal.
As described in greater detail below,
if BX has calculated improperly and the
market deems the proposed fees to be
unfair, inequitable, or unreasonably
discriminatory, firms can discontinue
the use of their data because the
proposed product is entirely optional to
all parties. Firms are not required to
purchase data and BX is not required to
make data available or to offer specific
pricing alternatives for potential
purchases. BX can discontinue offering
a pricing alternative (as it has in the
past) and firms can discontinue their
use at any time and for any reason (as
they often do), including due to their
assessment of the reasonableness of fees
charged. BX continues to establish and
revise pricing policies aimed at
increasing fairness and equitable
allocation of fees among Subscribers.
BX believes that periodically it must
adjust the Subscriber fees to reflect
market forces. BX believes it is an
appropriate time to adjust this fee to
more accurately reflect the investments
made to enhance this product through
capacity upgrades. This also reflects that
the market for this information is highly
competitive and continually evolves as
products develop and change.
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
B. Self-Regulatory Organization’s
Statement on Burden on Competition
The Exchange does not believe that
the proposed rule change will result in
any burden on competition that is not
necessary or appropriate in furtherance
of the purposes of the Act, as amended.
Notwithstanding its determination that
the Commission may rely upon
competition to establish fair and
equitably allocated fees for market data,
the NetCoalition court found that the
Commission had not, in that case,
compiled a record that adequately
supported its conclusion that the market
for the data at issue in the case was
competitive. BX believes that a record
may readily be established to
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:32 Jan 05, 2016
Jkt 238001
demonstrate the competitive nature of
the market in question.
There is intense competition between
trading platforms that provide
transaction execution and routing
services and proprietary data products.
Transaction execution and proprietary
data products are complementary in that
market data is both an input and a
byproduct of the execution service. In
fact, market data and trade execution are
a paradigmatic example of joint
products with joint costs. Data products
are valuable to many end Subscribers
only insofar as they provide information
that end Subscribers expect will assist
them or their customers in making
trading decisions.
The costs of producing market data
include not only the costs of the data
distribution infrastructure, but also the
costs of designing, maintaining, and
operating the exchange’s transaction
execution platform and the cost of
regulating the exchange to ensure its fair
operation and maintain investor
confidence. The total return that a
trading platform earns reflects the
revenues it receives from both products
and the joint costs it incurs. Moreover,
an exchange’s customers view the costs
of transaction executions and of data as
a unified cost of doing business with the
exchange. A broker-dealer (‘‘BD’’) will
direct orders to a particular exchange
only if the expected revenues from
executing trades on the exchange exceed
net transaction execution costs and the
cost of data that the BD chooses to buy
to support its trading decisions (or those
of its customers). The choice of data
products is, in turn, a product of the
value of the products in making
profitable trading decisions. If the cost
of the product exceeds its expected
value, the BD will choose not to buy it.
Moreover, as a BD chooses to direct
fewer orders to a particular exchange,
the value of the product to that BD
decreases, for two reasons. First, the
product will contain less information,
because executions of the BD’s orders
will not be reflected in it. Second, and
perhaps more important, the product
will be less valuable to that BD because
it does not provide information about
the venue to which it is directing its
orders. Data from the competing venue
to which the BD is directing orders will
become correspondingly more valuable.
Thus, an increase in the fees charged
for either transactions or data has the
potential to impair revenues from both
products. ‘‘No one disputes that
competition for order flow is ‘fierce’.’’
NetCoalition at 24. However, the
existence of fierce competition for order
flow implies a high degree of price
sensitivity on the part of BDs with order
PO 00000
Frm 00099
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
557
flow, since they may readily reduce
costs by directing orders toward the
lowest-cost trading venues. A BD that
shifted its order flow from one platform
to another in response to order
execution price differentials would both
reduce the value of that platform’s
market data and reduce its own need to
consume data from the disfavored
platform. Similarly, if a platform
increases its market data fees, the
change will affect the overall cost of
doing business with the platform, and
affected BDs will assess whether they
can lower their trading costs by
directing orders elsewhere and thereby
lessening the need for the more
expensive data.
Analyzing the cost of market data
distribution in isolation from the cost of
all of the inputs supporting the creation
of market data will inevitably
underestimate the cost of the data. Thus,
because it is impossible to create data
without a fast, technologically robust,
and well-regulated execution system,
system costs and regulatory costs affect
the price of market data. It would be
equally misleading, however, to
attribute all of the exchange’s costs to
the market data portion of an exchange’s
joint product. Rather, all of the
exchange’s costs are incurred for the
unified purposes of attracting order
flow, executing and/or routing orders,
and generating and selling data about
market activity. The total return that an
exchange earns reflects the revenues it
receives from the joint products and the
total costs of the joint products.
Competition among trading platforms
can be expected to constrain the
aggregate return each platform earns
from the sale of its joint products, but
different platforms may choose from a
range of possible, and equally
reasonable, pricing strategies as the
means of recovering total costs. BX pays
rebates to attract orders, charges
relatively low prices for market
information and charges relatively high
prices for accessing posted liquidity.
Other platforms may choose a strategy
of paying lower liquidity rebates to
attract orders, setting relatively low
prices for accessing posted liquidity,
and setting relatively high prices for
market information. Still others may
provide most data free of charge and
rely exclusively on transaction fees to
recover their costs. Finally, some
platforms may incentivize use by
providing opportunities for equity
ownership, which may allow them to
charge lower direct fees for executions
and data.
In this environment, there is no
economic basis for regulating maximum
prices for one of the joint products in an
E:\FR\FM\06JAN1.SGM
06JAN1
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
558
Federal Register / Vol. 81, No. 3 / Wednesday, January 6, 2016 / Notices
industry in which suppliers face
competitive constraints with regard to
the joint offering. Such regulation is
unnecessary because an ‘‘excessive’’
price for one of the joint products will
ultimately have to be reflected in lower
prices for other products sold by the
firm, or otherwise the firm will
experience a loss in the volume of its
sales that will be adverse to its overall
profitability. In other words, an increase
in the price of data will ultimately have
to be accompanied by a decrease in the
cost of executions, or the volume of both
data and executions will fall.
The level of competition and
contestability in the market is evident in
the numerous alternative venues that
compete for order flow, including
eleven SRO markets, as well as
internalizing BDs and various forms of
alternative trading systems (‘‘ATSs’’),
including dark pools and electronic
communication networks (‘‘ECNs’’).
Each SRO market competes to produce
transaction reports via trade executions,
and two FINRA-regulated TRFs compete
to attract internalized transaction
reports. It is common for BDs to further
and exploit this competition by sending
their order flow and transaction reports
to multiple markets, rather than
providing them all to a single market.
Competitive markets for order flow,
executions, and transaction reports
provide pricing discipline for the inputs
of proprietary data products.
The large number of SROs, TRFs, BDs,
and ATSs that currently produce
proprietary data or are currently capable
of producing it provides further pricing
discipline for proprietary data products.
Each SRO, TRF, ATS, and BD is
currently permitted to produce
proprietary data products, and many
currently do or have announced plans to
do so, including BX, NYSE, NYSE MKT,
NYSE Arca, and BATS/Direct Edge.
Any ATS or BD can combine with any
other ATS, BD, or multiple ATSs or BDs
to produce joint proprietary data
products. Additionally, order routers
and market data vendors can facilitate
single or multiple BDs’ production of
proprietary data products. The potential
sources of proprietary products are
virtually limitless. Notably, the
potential sources of data include the
BDs that submit trade reports to TRFs
and that have the ability to consolidate
and distribute their data without the
involvement of FINRA or an exchangeoperated TRF.
The fact that proprietary data from
ATSs, BDs, and vendors can by-pass
SROs is significant in two respects.
First, non-SROs can compete directly
with SROs for the production and sale
of proprietary data products, as BATS
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:32 Jan 05, 2016
Jkt 238001
and NYSE Arca did before registering as
exchanges by publishing proprietary
book data on the internet. Second,
because a single order or transaction
report can appear in a core data product,
an SRO proprietary product, and/or a
non-SRO proprietary product, the data
available in proprietary products is
exponentially greater than the actual
number of orders and transaction
reports that exist in the marketplace.
In addition to the competition and
price discipline described above, the
market for proprietary data products is
also highly contestable because market
entry is rapid, inexpensive, and
profitable. The history of electronic
trading is replete with examples of
entrants that swiftly grew into some of
the largest electronic trading platforms
and proprietary data producers:
Archipelago, Bloomberg Tradebook,
Island, RediBook, Attain, TracECN,
BATS Trading and BATS/Direct Edge. A
proliferation of dark pools and other
ATSs operate profitably with
fragmentary shares of consolidated
market volume.
Regulation NMS, by deregulating the
market for proprietary data, has
increased the contestability of that
market. While BDs have previously
published their proprietary data
individually, Regulation NMS
encourages market data vendors and
BDs to produce proprietary products
cooperatively in a manner never before
possible. Multiple market data vendors
already have the capability to aggregate
data and disseminate it on a profitable
scale, including Bloomberg and
Thomson Reuters. In Europe, Cinnober
aggregates and disseminates data from
over 40 brokers and multilateral trading
facilities.8
In this environment, a supercompetitive increase in the fees charged
for either transactions or data has the
potential to impair revenues from both
products. ‘‘No one disputes that
competition for order flow is ‘fierce’.’’
NetCoalition I at 539. The existence of
fierce competition for order flow
implies a high degree of price sensitivity
on the part of BDs with order flow, since
they may readily reduce costs by
directing orders toward the lowest-cost
trading venues. A BD that shifted its
order flow from one platform to another
in response to order execution price
differentials would both reduce the
value of that platform’s market data and
reduce its own need to consume data
from the disfavored platform. If a
platform increases its market data fees,
the change will affect the overall cost of
8 See https://www.cinnober.com/boat-tradereporting.
PO 00000
Frm 00100
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
doing business with the platform, and
affected BDs will assess whether they
can lower their trading costs by
directing orders elsewhere and thereby
lessening the need for the more
expensive data.
C. Self-Regulatory Organization’s
Statement on Comments on the
Proposed Rule Change Received From
Members, Participants, or Others
Written comments were neither
solicited nor received.
III. Date of Effectiveness of the
Proposed Rule Change and Timing for
Commission Action
The foregoing rule change has become
effective pursuant to section
19(b)(3)(A)(ii) of the Act.9 At any time
within 60 days of the filing of the
proposed rule change, the Commission
summarily may temporarily suspend
such rule change if it appears to the
Commission that such action is
necessary or appropriate in the public
interest, for the protection of investors,
or otherwise in furtherance of the
purposes of the Act. If the Commission
takes such action, the Commission shall
institute proceedings to determine
whether the proposed rule should be
approved or disapproved.
IV. Solicitation of Comments
Interested persons are invited to
submit written data, views, and
arguments concerning the foregoing,
including whether the proposed rule
change, as amended, is consistent with
the Act. Comments may be submitted by
any of the following methods:
Electronic Comments
• Use the Commission’s Internet
comment form (https://www.sec.gov/
rules/sro.shtml); or
• Send an email to rule-comments@
sec.gov. Please include File Number SR–
BX–2015–084 on the subject line.
Paper Comments
• Send paper comments in triplicate
to Secretary, Securities and Exchange
Commission, 100 F Street NE.,
Washington, DC 20549–1090.
All submissions should refer to File
Number SR–BX–2015–084. This file
number should be included on the
subject line if email is used. To help the
Commission process and review your
comments more efficiently, please use
only one method. The Commission will
post all comments on the Commission’s
Internet Web site (https://www.sec.gov/
rules/sro.shtml). Copies of the
submission, all subsequent
9 15
E:\FR\FM\06JAN1.SGM
U.S.C. 78s(b)(3)(a)(ii).
06JAN1
Federal Register / Vol. 81, No. 3 / Wednesday, January 6, 2016 / Notices
amendments, all written statements
with respect to the proposed rule
change that are filed with the
Commission, and all written
communications relating to the
proposed rule change between the
Commission and any person, other than
those that may be withheld from the
public in accordance with the
provisions of 5 U.S.C. 552, will be
available for Web site viewing and
printing in the Commission’s Public
Reference Room on official business
days between the hours of 10:00 a.m.
and 3:00 p.m. Copies of such filing also
will be available for inspection and
copying at the principal offices of the
Exchange. All comments received will
be posted without change; the
Commission does not edit personal
identifying information from
submissions. You should submit only
information that you wish to make
available publicly. All submissions
should refer to File Number SR–BX–
2015–084, and should be submitted on
or before January 27, 2016.
For the Commission, by the Division of
Trading and Markets, pursuant to delegated
authority.10
Jill M. Peterson,
Assistant Secretary.
[FR Doc. 2015–33209 Filed 1–5–16; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 8011–01–P
DEPARTMENT OF STATE
[Public Notice: 9397]
Notifications to the Congress of
Proposed Commercial Export Licenses
Bureau of Political-Military
Affairs, Directorate of Defense Trade
Controls, Department of State.
ACTION: Notice.
AGENCY:
Notice is hereby given that
the Department of State has forwarded
the attached Notifications of Proposed
Export Licenses to the Congress on the
dates indicated on the attachments
pursuant to sections 36(c) and 36(d),
and in compliance with section 36(f), of
the Arms Export Control Act.
DATES: Effective Date: As shown on each
of the 48 letters.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: Ms.
Lisa V. Aguirre, Directorate of Defense
Trade Controls, Department of State,
telephone (202) 663–2830; email
DDTCResponseTeam@state.gov. ATTN:
Congressional Notification of Licenses.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: Section
36(f) of the Arms Export Control Act (22
U.S.C. 2778) mandates that notifications
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
SUMMARY:
10 17
CFR 200.30–3(a)(12).
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:32 Jan 05, 2016
Jkt 238001
to the Congress pursuant to sections
36(c) and 36(d) must be published in the
Federal Register when they are
transmitted to Congress or as soon
thereafter as practicable.
Following are such notifications to
the Congress:
March 11, 2015 (Transmittal No. DDTC 14–
143)
Honorable John A. Boehner, Speaker of the
House of Representatives
Dear Mr. Speaker:
Pursuant to Section 36(c) of the Arms Export
Control Act, I am transmitting certification of
a proposed license for the export of firearm
parts and components abroad controlled
under Category I of the United States
Munitions List in amount of $1,000,000 or
more.
The transaction contained in the attached
certification involves the export of Sig Sauer
rifles model Sig 516 full-auto rifles and
accessories, model 516G2 full-auto rifles and
accessories, and SD rifle silencers to the
Indonesian Defence Force in Indonesia.
The United States government is prepared to
license the export of these items having taken
into account political, military, economic,
human rights, and arms control
considerations.
More detailed information is contained in the
formal certification which, though
unclassified, contains business information
submitted to the Department of State by the
applicant, publication of which could cause
competitive harm to the United States firm
concerned.
Sincerely,
Julia Frifield
Assistant Secretary Legislative Affairs
March 16, 2015 (Transmittal No. DDTC 14–
110)
Honorable John A. Boehner, Speaker of the
House of Representatives
Dear Mr. Speaker:
Pursuant to Section 36(c) of the Arms Export
Control Act, I am transmitting certification of
a proposed license for the export of defense
articles, to include technical data, and
defense services in the amount of
$100,000,000 or more.
The transaction contained in the attached
certification involves the export of defense
articles, including technical data, and
defense services to the Republic of Korea to
support the Patriot Guidance Enhances
Missile-Tactical (GEM–T) upgrade program
and the Missile Assembly/Disassembly
Facility (MADF).
The United States government is prepared to
license the export of these items having taken
into account political, military, economic,
human rights, and arms control
considerations.
More detailed information is contained in the
formal certification which, though
unclassified, contains business information
submitted to the Department of State by the
applicant, publication of which could cause
competitive harm to the United States firm
concerned.
PO 00000
Frm 00101
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
559
Sincerely,
Julia Frifield,
Assistant Secretary Legislative Affairs
March 17, 2015 (Transmittal No. DDTC 14–
141)
Honorable John A. Boehner, Speaker of the
House of Representatives
Dear Mr. Speaker:
Pursuant to Section 36(c) of the Arms Export
Control Act, I am transmitting certification of
a proposed license for the export of technical
data and defense services in the amount of
$50,000,000 or more.
The transaction contained in the attached
certification involves the transfer of technical
data and defense services to support the
Falcon 9 integration and launch of the
JCSAT–14 Commercial Communication
Satellite from Cape Canaveral.
The United States government is prepared to
license the export of these items having taken
into account political, military, economic,
human rights, and arms control
considerations.
More detailed information is contained in the
formal certification which, though
unclassified, contains business information
submitted to the Department of State by the
applicant, publication of which could cause
competitive harm to the United States firm
concerned.
Sincerely,
Julia Frifield,
Assistant Secretary Legislative Affairs
March 18, 2015 (Transmittal No. DDTC 14–
151)
Honorable John A. Boehner, Speaker of the
House of Representatives
Dear Mr. Speaker:
Pursuant to Section 36(c) of the Arms Export
Control Act, I am transmitting certification of
a proposed license for the export of firearms
and components abroad controlled under
Category I of the United States Munitions List
in amount of $1,000,000 or more.
The transaction contained in the attached
certification involves the export of various
rifles, pistols, and revolvers with spare parts
and accessories to Smith & Wesson
Distributing, Inc. in Belgium.
The United States Government is prepared to
license the export of these items having taken
into account political, military, economic,
human rights, and arms control
considerations.
More detailed information is contained in the
formal certification which, though
unclassified, contains business information
submitted to the Department of State by the
applicant, publication of which could cause
competitive harm to the United States firm
concerned.
Sincerely,
Julia Frifield
Assistant Secretary Legislative Affairs
March 20, 2015 (Transmittal No. DDTC 14–
153)
Honorable John A. Boehner, Speaker of the
House of Representatives
Dear Mr. Speaker:
E:\FR\FM\06JAN1.SGM
06JAN1
Agencies
[Federal Register Volume 81, Number 3 (Wednesday, January 6, 2016)]
[Notices]
[Pages 555-559]
From the Federal Register Online via the Government Publishing Office [www.gpo.gov]
[FR Doc No: 2015-33209]
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
SECURITIES AND EXCHANGE COMMISSION
[Release No. 34-76796; File No. SR-BX-2015-084)]
Self-Regulatory Organizations; NASDAQ OMX BX, Inc.; Notice of
Filing and Immediate Effectiveness of Proposed Rule Change To Modify
the Fees for Managed Data Solutions
December 30, 2015.
Pursuant to section 19(b)(1) of the Securities Exchange Act of 1934
(``Act''),\1\ and Rule 19b-4 thereunder,\2\ notice is hereby given that
on December 18, 2015, The NASDAQ OMX BX, Inc (``BX'') filed with the
Securities and Exchange Commission (``Commission'') the proposed rule
change as described in Items I, II, and III below, which Items have
been prepared by BX. The Commission is publishing this notice to
solicit comments on the proposed rule change from interested persons.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1\ 15 U.S.C. 78s(b)(1).
\2\ 17 CFR 240.19b-4.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
I. Self-Regulatory Organization's Statement of the Terms of the
Substance of the Proposed Rule Change
BX proposes to modify the charges to be paid for Managed Data
Solutions (``MDS''). While the changes proposed herein are effective
upon filing, the Exchange has designated that the amendments be
operative on January 1, 2016.
The text of the proposed rule change is below. Proposed new
language is italicized; proposed deletions are bracketed.
Rules of NASDAQ OMX BX
Equity Rules
* * * * *
7026. Distribution Models
(a) Managed Data Solutions.
Distributors and Subscribers of Managed Data Solutions products
containing BX TotalView data (non-display use only) shall pay the
following fees:
Fee Schedule for Managed Data
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Solutions Price
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Managed Data Solutions Administration Fee (for $[750]1,500/mo Per Distributor.
the right to offer Managed Data Solutions to
client organizations).
BX Depth Data Professional Managed Data $1[0]50/mo Per Subscriber.
Solutions Subscriber Fee (Internal Use Only and
includes BX TotalView).
BX Depth Data Managed Data Solutions Non- $20/mo Per Subscriber.
Professional Subscriber Fee (Internal Use Only
and includes BX TotalView).
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
[[Page 556]]
(b) No change.
* * * * *
II. Self-Regulatory Organization's Statement of the Purpose of, and
Statutory Basis for, the Proposed Rule Change
In its filing with the Commission, BX included statements
concerning the purpose of and basis for the proposed rule change and
discussed any comments it received on the proposed rule change. The
text of these statements may be examined at the places specified in
Item IV below. BX has prepared summaries, set forth in Sections A, B,
and C below, of the most significant aspects of such statements.
A. Self-Regulatory Organization's Statement of the Purpose of, and
Statutory Basis for, the Proposed Rule Change
1. Purpose
The purpose of the proposed rule change is to increase the charges
to be paid by distributors and subscribers of Managed Data Solutions
products containing BX TotalView data (non-display use only).
Specifically, the Exchange proposes to increase the fee charged to
distributors for the right to offer Managed Data Solutions to client
organizations to $1,500 per month per distributor (``MDS Administration
Fee''), and the fee charged to professional subscribers to $150 per
month per subscriber (``MDS Subscriber Fee''). This proposed rule
change will not affect the pricing for non-professional subscribers.
MDS is a data delivery option available to distributors of BX
TotalView. Under the MDS fee structure, distributors may provide data
feeds, Application Programming Interfaces (APIs) or similar automated
delivery solutions to client organizations with only limited
entitlement controls. Through this program, BX offers a much simpler
administration process for MDS distributors and subscribers, reducing
the burden and cost of administration.
Subscribers of MDS may use the information for internal purposes
only and may not distribute the information outside of their
organization. MDS presents opportunities for small and mid-size firms
to achieve significant cost savings over the cost of data feeds.
Both the MDS Administration Fee and MDS Subscriber Fee have not
changed since their introduction in 2013. Nevertheless, both
distributors and subscribers reap the benefits of BX's constant focus
on the performance and enhancements to these offerings. As such, BX
recently completed a technology refresh to ensure that its data feeds
continue to achieve a high level of performance and resiliency. The
Exchange has also upgraded and refreshed its disaster recovery
capabilities, adding to the increased focus on redundancy and
resiliency.
2. Statutory Basis
The Exchange believes that the proposed rule change is consistent
with the provisions of section 6 of the Act,\3\ in general, and with
sections 6(b)(4) and 6(b)(5) of the Act,\4\ in particular, in that it
provides an equitable allocation of reasonable fees among Subscribers
and recipients of BX data and is not designed to permit unfair
discrimination between them. BX's proposal to increase the MDS
Administration Fee and MDS Subscriber Fee is also consistent with the
Act in that it reflects an equitable allocation of reasonable fees. The
Commission has long recognized the fair and equitable and not
unreasonably discriminatory nature of assessing different fees for
distributors and professional and non-professional users of the same
data. BX also believes it is equitable to assess a higher fee per
professional user than to an ordinary non-professional user due to the
enhanced flexibility, lower overall costs and value that it offers
distributors.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\3\ 15 U.S.C. 78f.
\4\ 15 U.S.C. 78f(b)(4) and (5).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
In adopting Regulation NMS, the Commission granted self-regulatory
organizations and broker-dealers increased authority and flexibility to
offer new and unique market data to the public.
The Commission concluded that Regulation NMS--by deregulating the
market in proprietary data--would itself further the Act's goals of
facilitating efficiency and competition:
[E]fficiency is promoted when broker-dealers who do not need the
data beyond the prices, sizes, market center identifications of the
NBBO and consolidated last sale information are not required to
receive (and pay for) such data. The Commission also believes that
efficiency is promoted when broker-dealers may choose to receive
(and pay for) additional market data based on their own internal
analysis of the need for such data.\5\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\5\ See Securities Exchange Act Release No. 51808 (June 9,
2005), 70 FR 37496 (June 29, 2005).
By removing ``unnecessary regulatory restrictions'' on the ability of
exchanges to sell their own data, Regulation NMS advanced the goals of
the Act and the principles reflected in its legislative history. If the
free market should determine whether proprietary data is sold to
broker-dealers at all, it follows that the price at which such data is
sold should be set by the market as well. BX TotalView is precisely the
sort of market data products that the Commission envisioned when it
adopted Regulation NMS.
The decision of the United States Court of Appeals for the District
of Columbia Circuit in NetCoalition v. SEC, 615 F.3d 525 (D.C. Cir.
2010) (``NetCoalition I''), upheld the Commission's reliance upon
competitive markets to set reasonable and equitably allocated fees for
market data. ``In fact, the legislative history indicates that the
Congress intended that the market system `evolve through the interplay
of competitive forces as unnecessary regulatory restrictions are
removed' and that the SEC wield its regulatory power `in those
situations where competition may not be sufficient,' such as in the
creation of a `consolidated transactional reporting system.'
NetCoalition I, at 535 (quoting H.R. Rep. No. 94-229, at 92 (1975), as
reprinted in 1975 U.S.C.C.A.N. 321, 323). The court agreed with the
Commission's conclusion that ``Congress intended that `competitive
forces should dictate the services and practices that constitute the
U.S. national market system for trading equity securities.' '' \6\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\6\ NetCoalition I, at 535.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The Court in NetCoalition I, while upholding the Commission's
conclusion that competitive forces may be relied upon to establish the
fairness of prices, nevertheless concluded that the record in that case
did not adequately support the Commission's conclusions as to the
competitive nature of the market for NYSE Arca's data product at issue
in that case. As explained below in BX's Statement on Burden on
Competition, however, BX believes that there is substantial evidence of
competition in the marketplace for data that was not in the record in
the NetCoalition I case, and that the Commission is entitled to rely
upon such evidence in concluding fees are the product of competition,
and therefore in accordance with the relevant statutory standards.\7\
Accordingly, any findings of the court with respect to that product may
not be
[[Page 557]]
relevant to the product at issue in this filing.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\7\ It should also be noted that section 916 of the Dodd-Frank
Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act of 2010 (``Dodd-Frank
Act'') has amended paragraph (A) of section 19(b)(3) of the Act, 15
U.S.C. 78s(b)(3), to make it clear that all exchange fees, including
fees for market data, may be filed by exchanges on an immediately
effective basis. See also NetCoalition v. SEC, 715 F.3d 342 (D.C.
Cir. 2013) (``NetCoalition II'') (finding no jurisdiction to review
Commission's non-suspension of immediately effective fee changes).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
BX believes that the allocation of the proposed fee is fair and
equitable in accordance with section 6(b)(4) of the Act, and not
unreasonably discriminatory in accordance with section 6(b)(5) of the
Act. As described above, the proposed fee is based on pricing
conventions and distinctions that exist in BX's current fee schedule.
These distinctions are each based on principles of fairness and equity
that have helped for many years to maintain fair, equitable, and not
unreasonably discriminatory fees, and that apply with equal or greater
force to the current proposal.
As described in greater detail below, if BX has calculated
improperly and the market deems the proposed fees to be unfair,
inequitable, or unreasonably discriminatory, firms can discontinue the
use of their data because the proposed product is entirely optional to
all parties. Firms are not required to purchase data and BX is not
required to make data available or to offer specific pricing
alternatives for potential purchases. BX can discontinue offering a
pricing alternative (as it has in the past) and firms can discontinue
their use at any time and for any reason (as they often do), including
due to their assessment of the reasonableness of fees charged. BX
continues to establish and revise pricing policies aimed at increasing
fairness and equitable allocation of fees among Subscribers.
BX believes that periodically it must adjust the Subscriber fees to
reflect market forces. BX believes it is an appropriate time to adjust
this fee to more accurately reflect the investments made to enhance
this product through capacity upgrades. This also reflects that the
market for this information is highly competitive and continually
evolves as products develop and change.
B. Self-Regulatory Organization's Statement on Burden on Competition
The Exchange does not believe that the proposed rule change will
result in any burden on competition that is not necessary or
appropriate in furtherance of the purposes of the Act, as amended.
Notwithstanding its determination that the Commission may rely upon
competition to establish fair and equitably allocated fees for market
data, the NetCoalition court found that the Commission had not, in that
case, compiled a record that adequately supported its conclusion that
the market for the data at issue in the case was competitive. BX
believes that a record may readily be established to demonstrate the
competitive nature of the market in question.
There is intense competition between trading platforms that provide
transaction execution and routing services and proprietary data
products. Transaction execution and proprietary data products are
complementary in that market data is both an input and a byproduct of
the execution service. In fact, market data and trade execution are a
paradigmatic example of joint products with joint costs. Data products
are valuable to many end Subscribers only insofar as they provide
information that end Subscribers expect will assist them or their
customers in making trading decisions.
The costs of producing market data include not only the costs of
the data distribution infrastructure, but also the costs of designing,
maintaining, and operating the exchange's transaction execution
platform and the cost of regulating the exchange to ensure its fair
operation and maintain investor confidence. The total return that a
trading platform earns reflects the revenues it receives from both
products and the joint costs it incurs. Moreover, an exchange's
customers view the costs of transaction executions and of data as a
unified cost of doing business with the exchange. A broker-dealer
(``BD'') will direct orders to a particular exchange only if the
expected revenues from executing trades on the exchange exceed net
transaction execution costs and the cost of data that the BD chooses to
buy to support its trading decisions (or those of its customers). The
choice of data products is, in turn, a product of the value of the
products in making profitable trading decisions. If the cost of the
product exceeds its expected value, the BD will choose not to buy it.
Moreover, as a BD chooses to direct fewer orders to a particular
exchange, the value of the product to that BD decreases, for two
reasons. First, the product will contain less information, because
executions of the BD's orders will not be reflected in it. Second, and
perhaps more important, the product will be less valuable to that BD
because it does not provide information about the venue to which it is
directing its orders. Data from the competing venue to which the BD is
directing orders will become correspondingly more valuable.
Thus, an increase in the fees charged for either transactions or
data has the potential to impair revenues from both products. ``No one
disputes that competition for order flow is `fierce'.'' NetCoalition at
24. However, the existence of fierce competition for order flow implies
a high degree of price sensitivity on the part of BDs with order flow,
since they may readily reduce costs by directing orders toward the
lowest-cost trading venues. A BD that shifted its order flow from one
platform to another in response to order execution price differentials
would both reduce the value of that platform's market data and reduce
its own need to consume data from the disfavored platform. Similarly,
if a platform increases its market data fees, the change will affect
the overall cost of doing business with the platform, and affected BDs
will assess whether they can lower their trading costs by directing
orders elsewhere and thereby lessening the need for the more expensive
data.
Analyzing the cost of market data distribution in isolation from
the cost of all of the inputs supporting the creation of market data
will inevitably underestimate the cost of the data. Thus, because it is
impossible to create data without a fast, technologically robust, and
well-regulated execution system, system costs and regulatory costs
affect the price of market data. It would be equally misleading,
however, to attribute all of the exchange's costs to the market data
portion of an exchange's joint product. Rather, all of the exchange's
costs are incurred for the unified purposes of attracting order flow,
executing and/or routing orders, and generating and selling data about
market activity. The total return that an exchange earns reflects the
revenues it receives from the joint products and the total costs of the
joint products.
Competition among trading platforms can be expected to constrain
the aggregate return each platform earns from the sale of its joint
products, but different platforms may choose from a range of possible,
and equally reasonable, pricing strategies as the means of recovering
total costs. BX pays rebates to attract orders, charges relatively low
prices for market information and charges relatively high prices for
accessing posted liquidity. Other platforms may choose a strategy of
paying lower liquidity rebates to attract orders, setting relatively
low prices for accessing posted liquidity, and setting relatively high
prices for market information. Still others may provide most data free
of charge and rely exclusively on transaction fees to recover their
costs. Finally, some platforms may incentivize use by providing
opportunities for equity ownership, which may allow them to charge
lower direct fees for executions and data.
In this environment, there is no economic basis for regulating
maximum prices for one of the joint products in an
[[Page 558]]
industry in which suppliers face competitive constraints with regard to
the joint offering. Such regulation is unnecessary because an
``excessive'' price for one of the joint products will ultimately have
to be reflected in lower prices for other products sold by the firm, or
otherwise the firm will experience a loss in the volume of its sales
that will be adverse to its overall profitability. In other words, an
increase in the price of data will ultimately have to be accompanied by
a decrease in the cost of executions, or the volume of both data and
executions will fall.
The level of competition and contestability in the market is
evident in the numerous alternative venues that compete for order flow,
including eleven SRO markets, as well as internalizing BDs and various
forms of alternative trading systems (``ATSs''), including dark pools
and electronic communication networks (``ECNs''). Each SRO market
competes to produce transaction reports via trade executions, and two
FINRA-regulated TRFs compete to attract internalized transaction
reports. It is common for BDs to further and exploit this competition
by sending their order flow and transaction reports to multiple
markets, rather than providing them all to a single market. Competitive
markets for order flow, executions, and transaction reports provide
pricing discipline for the inputs of proprietary data products.
The large number of SROs, TRFs, BDs, and ATSs that currently
produce proprietary data or are currently capable of producing it
provides further pricing discipline for proprietary data products. Each
SRO, TRF, ATS, and BD is currently permitted to produce proprietary
data products, and many currently do or have announced plans to do so,
including BX, NYSE, NYSE MKT, NYSE Arca, and BATS/Direct Edge.
Any ATS or BD can combine with any other ATS, BD, or multiple ATSs
or BDs to produce joint proprietary data products. Additionally, order
routers and market data vendors can facilitate single or multiple BDs'
production of proprietary data products. The potential sources of
proprietary products are virtually limitless. Notably, the potential
sources of data include the BDs that submit trade reports to TRFs and
that have the ability to consolidate and distribute their data without
the involvement of FINRA or an exchange-operated TRF.
The fact that proprietary data from ATSs, BDs, and vendors can by-
pass SROs is significant in two respects. First, non-SROs can compete
directly with SROs for the production and sale of proprietary data
products, as BATS and NYSE Arca did before registering as exchanges by
publishing proprietary book data on the internet. Second, because a
single order or transaction report can appear in a core data product,
an SRO proprietary product, and/or a non-SRO proprietary product, the
data available in proprietary products is exponentially greater than
the actual number of orders and transaction reports that exist in the
marketplace.
In addition to the competition and price discipline described
above, the market for proprietary data products is also highly
contestable because market entry is rapid, inexpensive, and profitable.
The history of electronic trading is replete with examples of entrants
that swiftly grew into some of the largest electronic trading platforms
and proprietary data producers: Archipelago, Bloomberg Tradebook,
Island, RediBook, Attain, TracECN, BATS Trading and BATS/Direct Edge. A
proliferation of dark pools and other ATSs operate profitably with
fragmentary shares of consolidated market volume.
Regulation NMS, by deregulating the market for proprietary data,
has increased the contestability of that market. While BDs have
previously published their proprietary data individually, Regulation
NMS encourages market data vendors and BDs to produce proprietary
products cooperatively in a manner never before possible. Multiple
market data vendors already have the capability to aggregate data and
disseminate it on a profitable scale, including Bloomberg and Thomson
Reuters. In Europe, Cinnober aggregates and disseminates data from over
40 brokers and multilateral trading facilities.\8\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\8\ See https://www.cinnober.com/boat-trade-reporting.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
In this environment, a super-competitive increase in the fees
charged for either transactions or data has the potential to impair
revenues from both products. ``No one disputes that competition for
order flow is `fierce'.'' NetCoalition I at 539. The existence of
fierce competition for order flow implies a high degree of price
sensitivity on the part of BDs with order flow, since they may readily
reduce costs by directing orders toward the lowest-cost trading venues.
A BD that shifted its order flow from one platform to another in
response to order execution price differentials would both reduce the
value of that platform's market data and reduce its own need to consume
data from the disfavored platform. If a platform increases its market
data fees, the change will affect the overall cost of doing business
with the platform, and affected BDs will assess whether they can lower
their trading costs by directing orders elsewhere and thereby lessening
the need for the more expensive data.
C. Self-Regulatory Organization's Statement on Comments on the Proposed
Rule Change Received From Members, Participants, or Others
Written comments were neither solicited nor received.
III. Date of Effectiveness of the Proposed Rule Change and Timing for
Commission Action
The foregoing rule change has become effective pursuant to section
19(b)(3)(A)(ii) of the Act.\9\ At any time within 60 days of the filing
of the proposed rule change, the Commission summarily may temporarily
suspend such rule change if it appears to the Commission that such
action is necessary or appropriate in the public interest, for the
protection of investors, or otherwise in furtherance of the purposes of
the Act. If the Commission takes such action, the Commission shall
institute proceedings to determine whether the proposed rule should be
approved or disapproved.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\9\ 15 U.S.C. 78s(b)(3)(a)(ii).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
IV. Solicitation of Comments
Interested persons are invited to submit written data, views, and
arguments concerning the foregoing, including whether the proposed rule
change, as amended, is consistent with the Act. Comments may be
submitted by any of the following methods:
Electronic Comments
Use the Commission's Internet comment form (https://www.sec.gov/rules/sro.shtml); or
Send an email to rule-comments@sec.gov. Please include
File Number SR-BX-2015-084 on the subject line.
Paper Comments
Send paper comments in triplicate to Secretary, Securities
and Exchange Commission, 100 F Street NE., Washington, DC 20549-1090.
All submissions should refer to File Number SR-BX-2015-084. This file
number should be included on the subject line if email is used. To help
the Commission process and review your comments more efficiently,
please use only one method. The Commission will post all comments on
the Commission's Internet Web site (https://www.sec.gov/rules/sro.shtml). Copies of the submission, all subsequent
[[Page 559]]
amendments, all written statements with respect to the proposed rule
change that are filed with the Commission, and all written
communications relating to the proposed rule change between the
Commission and any person, other than those that may be withheld from
the public in accordance with the provisions of 5 U.S.C. 552, will be
available for Web site viewing and printing in the Commission's Public
Reference Room on official business days between the hours of 10:00
a.m. and 3:00 p.m. Copies of such filing also will be available for
inspection and copying at the principal offices of the Exchange. All
comments received will be posted without change; the Commission does
not edit personal identifying information from submissions. You should
submit only information that you wish to make available publicly. All
submissions should refer to File Number SR-BX-2015-084, and should be
submitted on or before January 27, 2016.
For the Commission, by the Division of Trading and Markets,
pursuant to delegated authority.\10\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\10\ 17 CFR 200.30-3(a)(12).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Jill M. Peterson,
Assistant Secretary.
[FR Doc. 2015-33209 Filed 1-5-16; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 8011-01-P