Self-Regulatory Organizations; NASDAQ OMX BX, Inc.; Notice of Filing and Immediate Effectiveness of Proposed Rule Change To Amend Section 4 of Chapter XV of the BX Options Rules, 38757-38762 [2013-15373]
Download as PDF
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 124 / Thursday, June 27, 2013 / Notices
A. Self-Regulatory Organization’s
Statement of the Purpose of, and
Statutory Basis for, the Proposed Rule
Change
SECURITIES AND EXCHANGE
COMMISSION
[Release No. 34–69821; File No. SR–BX–
2013–040]
1. Purpose
Self-Regulatory Organizations;
NASDAQ OMX BX, Inc.; Notice of Filing
and Immediate Effectiveness of
Proposed Rule Change To Amend
Section 4 of Chapter XV of the BX
Options Rules
June 21, 2013.
Pursuant to Section 19(b)(1) of the
Securities Exchange Act of 1934
(‘‘Act’’) 1, and Rule 19b–4 thereunder,2
notice is hereby given that on June 11,
2013, NASDAQ OMX BX, Inc. (‘‘BX’’ or
‘‘Exchange’’) filed with the Securities
and Exchange Commission (‘‘SEC’’ or
‘‘Commission’’) the proposed rule
change as described in Items I, II, and
III below, which Items have been
prepared by the Exchange. The
Commission is publishing this notice to
solicit comments on the proposed rule
change from interested persons.
I. Self-Regulatory Organization’s
Statement of the Terms of Substance of
the Proposed Rule Change
The Exchange proposes to amend
Section 4 of Chapter XV of the BX
Options Rules setting forth the fees for
options market data known as BX Top
of Market Options (‘‘BX Top’’) and BX
Depth of Market Options (‘‘BX Depth’’).
The text of the proposed rule change is
also available on the Exchange’s Web
site at https://
nasdaqomxbx.cchwallstreet.com, at the
principal office of the Exchange, and at
the Commission’s Public Reference
Room.
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
II. Self-Regulatory Organization’s
Statement of the Purpose of, and
Statutory Basis for, the Proposed Rule
Change
In its filing with the Commission, the
Exchange included statements
concerning the purpose of and basis for
the proposed rule change and discussed
any comments it received on the
proposed rule change. The text of these
statements may be examined at the
places specified in Item IV below. The
Exchange has prepared summaries, set
forth in sections A, B, and C below, of
the most significant aspects of such
statements.
1 15
2 17
U.S.C. 78s(b)(1).
CFR 240.19b–4.
VerDate Mar<15>2010
18:12 Jun 26, 2013
The Exchange proposes to amend
Section 4 of Chapter XV to set forth the
fees for options market data already
distributed as BX Top and BX Depth.
The Exchange has been offering the BX
Top and BX Depth options market data
free of charge for almost a year since the
launch of the BX Options Market. The
Exchange now proposes to institute fees
for recipients of BX Top and BX Depth
data, with a free trial offer for certain
data recipients.
BX Depth is currently described in the
Exchange’s option rules at subsection
(a)(3)(A) of Chapter VI, Section 1 as a
data package that includes quotation
information for individual orders on the
BX book, last sale information for trades
executed on BX, and Order Imbalance
Information as set forth in BX Rules
Chapter VI, Section 8. Members use BX
Depth to ‘‘build’’ their view of the BX
book by adding individual orders that
appear in the data, and subtracting
individual orders that are executed.
BX Top is currently described in
subsection (a)(3)(B) of Chapter VI,
Section 1 as a data package that
includes the BX Best Bid and Offer (‘‘BX
BBO’’) and last sale information for
trades executed on BX. The BX BBO and
last sale information are identical to the
information that BX sends the Options
Price Regulatory Authority (‘‘OPRA’’)
and which OPRA disseminates via the
consolidated data feed for options.
BX proposes to set fees for BX Top
and BX Depth data that use elements of
the current fee structure for recipients of
BX TotalView and BX BBO,3 which are
equities market data products similar to
BX Top and BX Depth. First, the
Exchange proposes to charge monthly
fees for firms that are Distributors of BX
Top and BX Depth data. Proposed
Section 4(b) of Chapter XV states that a
‘‘Distributor’’ of BX options market data
is any entity that receives a feed or data
file of BX data directly from BX or
indirectly through another entity and
then distributes the data either
internally (within that entity) or
externally (outside that entity).
Proposed subsection 4(b) also states that
all Distributors would be required to
execute a Distributor agreement with the
Exchange. The amount of the monthly
fees would depend on whether a
3 See
Jkt 229001
PO 00000
BX Rules 7023 and 7047.
Frm 00076
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
38757
Distributor is an ‘‘Internal Distributor’’
or ‘‘External Distributor.’’ 4
An Internal Distributor is a firm that
is permitted by agreement with the
Exchange to provide BX Top and BX
Depth data to internal Subscribers (i.e.,
users within their own organization).
Under the proposal, Distributors that
only use the BX data internally would
be charged monthly fee of $1,500 per
firm.
An External Distributor is a firm that
is permitted by agreement with the
Exchange to provide BX Top and BX
Depth data to both internal Subscribers
and to external Subscribers (i.e., users
outside of their own organization).
Distributors provide BX data externally
would be charged a monthly fee of
$2,000 per firm. The fee paid by an
External Distributor includes the
Internal Distributor Fee. The fee paid by
an Internal Distributor or an External
Distributor would allow access to both
the BX Top and BX Depth data feeds.
The Exchange also proposes to assess
Subscriber fees for BX Top and BX
Depth data on a Per Subscriber basis.5
These fees would vary based on whether
they are for Professional Subscribers or
Non-Professional Subscribers. Proposed
Section 4(f) states that the term ‘‘NonProfessional’’ shall have the same
meaning as in BX Rule 7023(b)(2). Rule
7023(b)(2) defines a ‘‘Non-Professional’’
as a natural person who is neither: (A)
Registered or qualified in any capacity
with the Commission, the Commodities
Futures Trading Commission, any state
securities agency, any securities
exchange or association, or any
commodities or futures contract market
or association; (B) engaged as an
‘‘investment adviser’’ as that term is
defined in Section 201(11) of the
Investment Advisors Act of 1940
(whether or not registered or qualified
under that Act); nor (C) employed by a
bank or other organization exempt from
registration under federal or state
securities laws to perform functions that
would require registration or
qualification if such functions were
performed for an organization not so
exempt.6 A Professional Subscriber is
any recipient that is not a NonProfessional.
4 Thus, a Distributor may pay either ‘‘Internal
Distributor’’ or ‘‘External Distributor’’ fees.
5 While the Subscriber fees would be paid by
firms (Internal Distributors and External
Distributors), some portion of the fees may be
passed through to Subscribers inside or outside the
firms (that is, to internal or external Subscribers).
6 The Exchange believes that Non-Professional
Subscribers of market data, in contrast to
Professional data Subscribers and Distributors,
often tend to be individual consumers, smaller
retail investors, and public customers.
E:\FR\FM\27JNN1.SGM
27JNN1
38758
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 124 / Thursday, June 27, 2013 / Notices
For BX Top data, the proposed
Subscriber fees are $5 per Professional
Subscriber; and $1 per Non-Professional
Subscriber. For BX Depth data, the
proposed fees are $10 per Professional
Subscriber; and $1 per Non-Professional
Subscriber.
The Exchange notes that for many
years, exchanges have engaged in and
the Commission has accepted the
practice of price differentiation, both in
the context of market data as well as in
the context of executions. With respect
to market data, NASDAQ and NYSE
Euronext (‘‘NYSE’’) in their capacities as
network processors and exchanges have
differentiated in pricing between
Professional and Non-Professional
market data Subscriber, often charging
Professionals many times more than
Non-Professionals for using the same
data. For example, NASDAQ currently
charges Non-Professionals $15 per
terminal for its NASDAQ Depth Data via
a standalone terminal, while
Professional Subscribers pay roughly
five times the Non-Professional rate.7
This reflects the value of the service to
various constituencies (i.e., lower prices
are charged to consumers with more
elastic demand) and allows both types
of investors to contribute to the high
fixed costs of operating an exchange
platform. The Exchange believes that
this differentiation for Professional and
Non-Professional data usage, as the
differentiation for Professional and NonProfessional Subscribers proposed in
this filing, is completely consistent with
past Commission precedent and
economic theory.8
The Exchange also proposes to assess
a monthly non-display enterprise
license fee. Proposed Section 4(c) of
Chapter XV states that an ‘‘Enterprise
License’’ entitles a Distributor to
provide BX Top and BX Depth market
data pursuant to this rule to an
unlimited number of non-display
devices 9 internally (within the firm)
without any additional Subscriber fees
associated with these non-display
devices. Under the proposal,
Distributors of BX Top and BX Depth
data, if they choose to subscribe to a
7 See
BX [sic] Rule 7023.
economic terms, charging lower fees to nonprofessional consumers increases overall economic
welfare by increasing output—in this case,
providing more data to more investors—and avoids
two equally undesirable alternatives: (i) Requiring
the firm to charge uniformly high prices that
constrict demand, or (ii) insisting on uniformly low
prices at marginal cost (potentially zero or close to
zero) that do not allow the firm to cover its fixed
costs and thereby lead to bankruptcy.
9 Non-display devices do not graphically show
(display) BX Top and BX Depth market data but
instead use the data for performance of analytic or
calculative functions (e.g. algorithms).
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
8 In
VerDate Mar<15>2010
18:12 Jun 26, 2013
Jkt 229001
non-display enterprise license, would
be charged a monthly enterprise license
fee or $2,500.
The non-display enterprise license is
in addition to the Internal or External
Distributor fees. Thus, a firm that has a
non-display enterprise license could
pay an Internal Distributor fee and the
Enterprise License fee and distribute
data to limitless number of non-display
devices (devices within the firm)
pursuant to the license without
incurring further fees for each internal
device. However, the enterprise license
does not allow external distribution
without incurring an External
Distributor fee and external Subscriber
fees, if applicable under the
circumstances.
Finally, the Exchange proposes a 30Day Free Trial Offer in proposed
subsection (g) of Section 4.10 In
particular, the 30-day waiver of the
Subscriber fees for BX options market
data pursuant to the rule extends to all
new individual (non-firm) Subscribers.
This fee waiver period will be applied
on a rolling basis, determined by the
date on which a new individual (nondistributor or firm) is first entitled by a
Distributor to receive access to BX
options market data. Subsection (g)
provides that a Distributor may only
provide this waiver to a specific
Subscriber at one time.
The Exchange notes that the
categories of BX Top and BX Depth
market data and fees compare favorably
with similar products offered by other
markets such as International Stock
Exchange (‘‘ISE’’), NYSE, NASDAQ
OMX PHLX (‘‘Phlx’’), and Chicago
Board Options Exchange (‘‘CBOE’’). For
example, ISE offers market data
products that are similar to BX Top: a
data feed that shows the top of the
market entitled TOP Quote Feed,11 and
a data feed that shows the top five price
levels entitled Depth of Market.12 NYSE
offers a market data product for Arca
and Amex that is similar to BX Top and
10 The Exchange also offers a 30-day free trial for
BX TotalView. See BX Rule 7023.
11 The ISE TOP Quote Feed has a monthly base
access fee of $3,000 applicable to professionals and
non-professionals plus a $20 variable device fee for
professionals and a no device fee for internal use
professionals; or a flat fixed enterprise fee of $5,000
for unlimited internal/external use and a $4,000 fee
for unlimited internal use. The Exchange notes that
the monthly fees for the ISE TOP Quote Feed are
higher than those proposed in this filing.
12 The ISE Depth of Market Feed has a monthly
base access fee of $5,000 applicable to professionals
and non-professionals plus a $50 variable device fee
for professionals and a $5 per device fee for external
distribution non-professionals; or a flat fixed
enterprise fee of $7,500 for unlimited internal use,
and $10,000 for unlimited internal/external use.
The Exchange notes that the monthly fees for ISE
Depth of Market are higher than those proposed in
this filing for a more robust product.
PO 00000
Frm 00077
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
BX Depth: a feed that shows top of book,
last sale, and depth of quote and is
entitled NYSE Arca Book for Options.13
Phlx offers a market data feed entitled
TOPO that is similar to BX Top and
shows orders and quotes at the top of
the market, as well as trades; and a Phlx
Depth feed that is similar to BX Depth
and shows the data in the TOPO data
feed as well as the depth of orders. 14
A subsidiary of CBOE for which CBOE
charges fees offers a market data feed
that is similar to BX Top and shows
BBO, last sale, and top of book data.15
And BATS offers Multicast PITCH,
which is their depth of market and last
sale feed similar to BX Depth.16
The Exchange believes that the
continued availability of BX Top and
BX Depth data feeds enhances
transparency, fosters competition among
orders and markets, and enables buyers
and sellers to obtain better prices.
2. Statutory Basis
BX believes that the proposed rule
change is consistent with the provisions
of Section 6 of the Act,17 in general, and
with Section 6(b)(4) of the Act,18 in
particular, in that it provides an
equitable allocation of reasonable fees
among recipients of BX data. In
adopting Regulation NMS, the
Commission granted self-regulatory
organizations and broker-dealers
increased authority and flexibility to
offer new and unique market data to the
public. It was believed that this
authority would expand the amount of
data available to consumers, and also
13 The fee for NYSE Arca Book for Options is
$3,000 per month for direct or indirect access,
$2,000 for external redistribution; and a $50 per
user professional user fee and $1 per user Nonprofessional user fee.
14 TOPO Plus Orders has a monthly fee of $4,000
for internal distributors or $5,000 for external
distributors plus a monthly fee of $1 per NonProfessional Subscribers and $20 for Professional
Subscribers. The Exchange notes that the monthly
fees for TOPO Plus Orders are higher than those
proposed in this filing. See Securities Exchange Act
Release No. 62194 (May 28, 2010), 75 FR 31830
(June 4, 2010) (SR–Phlx–2010–48) (order approving
proposal related to TOPO Plus Orders market data
fees).
15 The subsidiary is identified as Market Data
Express, LLC (‘‘MDX’’) by CBOE, which indicates
that the feed will also provide data regarding
contingency orders and complex strategies. The
monthly fee charged by CBOE for the data is $3,500
plus a $25 per user or device fee. See Securities
Exchange Act Release No. 63997 (March 1, 2011),
76 FR 12388 (March 7, 2011) (SR–CBOE–2011–014)
(notice of filing and immediate effectiveness). In the
filing, CBOE specifically references as similar
products the Phlx TOPO Plus Orders feed and the
ISE Depth of Market Feed.
16 BATS offers Multicast PITCH without charge
ostensibly to attract order flow to that exchange.
17 15 U.S.C. 78f.
18 15 U.S.C. 78f(b)(4).
E:\FR\FM\27JNN1.SGM
27JNN1
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 124 / Thursday, June 27, 2013 / Notices
spur innovation and competition for the
provision of market data.
The Commission concluded that
Regulation NMS—by deregulating the
market in proprietary data—would itself
further the Act’s goals of facilitating
efficiency and competition:
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
[E]fficiency is promoted when brokerdealers who do not need the data beyond the
prices, sizes, market center identifications of
the NBBO and consolidated last sale
information are not required to receive (and
pay for) such data. The Commission also
believes that efficiency is promoted when
broker-dealers may choose to receive (and
pay for) additional market data based on their
own internal analysis of the need for such
data.19
By removing ‘‘unnecessary regulatory
restrictions’’ on the ability of exchanges
to sell their own data, Regulation NMS
advanced the goals of the Act and the
principles reflected in its legislative
history. If the free market should
determine whether proprietary data is
sold to broker-dealers at all, it follows
that the price at which such data is sold
should be set by the market as well.
On July 21, 2010, President Barack
Obama signed into law H.R. 4173, the
Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and
Consumer Protection Act of 2010
(‘‘Dodd-Frank Act’’), which amended
Section 19 of the Act. Among other
things, Section 916 of the Dodd-Frank
Act amended paragraph (A) of Section
19(b)(3) of the Act by inserting the
phrase ‘‘on any person, whether or not
the person is a member of the selfregulatory organization’’ after ‘‘due, fee
or other charge imposed by the selfregulatory organization.’’ As a result, all
SRO rule proposals establishing or
changing dues, fees, or other charges are
immediately effective upon filing
regardless of whether such dues, fees, or
other charges are imposed on members
of the SRO, non-members, or both.
Section 916 further amended paragraph
(C) of Section 19(b)(3) of the Exchange
Act to read, in pertinent part, ‘‘At any
time within the 60-day period beginning
on the date of filing of such a proposed
rule change in accordance with the
provisions of paragraph (1) [of Section
19(b)], the Commission summarily may
temporarily suspend the change in the
rules of the self-regulatory organization
made thereby, if it appears to the
Commission that such action is
necessary or appropriate in the public
interest, for the protection of investors,
or otherwise in furtherance of the
purposes of this title. If the Commission
takes such action, the Commission shall
institute proceedings under paragraph
19 Securities Exchange Act Release No. 51808
(June 9, 2005), 70 FR 37496 (June 29, 2005).
VerDate Mar<15>2010
18:12 Jun 26, 2013
Jkt 229001
(2)(B) [of Section 19(b)] to determine
whether the proposed rule should be
approved or disapproved.’’
The decision of the United States
Court of Appeals for the District of
Columbia Circuit in NetCoalition v.
SEC, No. 09–1042 (D.C. Cir. 2010),
although reviewing a Commission
decision made prior to the effective date
of the Dodd-Frank Act, upheld the
Commission’s reliance upon
competitive markets to set reasonable
and equitably allocated fees for market
data. ‘‘In fact, the legislative history
indicates that the Congress intended
that the market system evolve through
the interplay of competitive forces as
unnecessary regulatory restrictions are
removed’ and that the SEC wield its
regulatory power in those situations
where competition may not be
sufficient, ‘such as in the creation of a
consolidated transactional reporting
system.’ ’’ NetCoalition, at 15 (quoting
H.R. Rep. No. 94–229, at 92 (1975), as
reprinted in 1975 U.S.C.C.A.N. 321,
323).
BX believes that the proposed fees are
fair and equitable, and not unreasonably
discriminatory. The proposed fees are
based on pricing conventions and
distinctions that currently exist in the
fee schedules of other exchanges,
including NASDAQ and PHLX. These
distinctions (e.g. Distributor versus
Subscriber, Professional versus NonProfessional, internal versus external
distribution, controlled versus
uncontrolled datafeed) are each based
on principles of fairness and equity that
have helped for many years to maintain
fair, equitable, and not unreasonably
discriminatory fees, and that apply with
equal or greater force to the current
proposal. BX believes that the BX Top
and BX Depth offerings is equitable in
that it provides an opportunity for all
Distributors and Subscribers,
Professional and Non-Professional, to
identical data without unfairly
discriminating against any.
Thus, if BX has calculated improperly
and the market deems the proposed fees
to be unfair, inequitable, or
unreasonably discriminatory, firms can
diminish or discontinue the use of their
data because the proposed fees are
entirely optional to all parties. Firms are
not required to choose to purchase BX
Top or BX Depth or to utilize any
specific pricing alternative. BX is not
required to make BX Top or BX Depth
available or to offer specific pricing
alternatives for potential purchases. BX
can discontinue offering a pricing
alternative (as it has in the past) and
firms can discontinue their use at any
time and for any reason (as they often
do), including due to their assessment of
PO 00000
Frm 00078
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
38759
the reasonableness of fees charged. BX
continues to establish and revise pricing
policies aimed at increasing fairness and
equitable allocation of fees among
Subscribers.
Competitive products similar to BX
Top or BX Depth are, as previously
discussed, offered by other exchanges,
albeit sometimes at higher prices. ISE
offers two data products similar to BX
Top that are called TOP Quote Feed and
Depth of Market and have fees higher
than those proposed in this filing.20
NYSE offers a market data product
similar to BX Top or BX Depth called
NYSE Arca Book of Options that has
market data for NYSE Arca and NYSE
Amex. Phlx offers a market data product
that is similar to ITTO.21 CBOE offers a
market data product that is similar to
BX Top.22 BATS offers a market data
product similar to BX Depth. Moreover,
the Exchange notes that, as a substitute
for exchange data, consolidated market
data (e.g. last sale, NBBO, current
quotes) are also available from securities
information processors such as OPRA.
B. Self-Regulatory Organization’s
Statement on Burden on Competition
BX does not believe that the proposed
rule change will result in any burden on
competition that is not necessary or
appropriate in furtherance of the
purposes of the Act, as amended.
Notwithstanding its determination that
the Commission may rely upon
competition to establish fair and
equitably allocated fees for market data,
the NetCoalition court found that the
Commission had not, in that case,
compiled a record that adequately
supported its conclusion that the market
for the data at issue in the case was
competitive. BX believes that a record
may readily be established to
demonstrate the competitive nature of
the market in question.
The proposal is, as described below,
pro-competitive. There is intense
competition between trading platforms
that provide transaction execution and
routing services and proprietary data
products. Transaction execution and
proprietary data products are
complementary in that market data is
both an input and a byproduct of the
execution service. In fact, market data
and trade execution are a paradigmatic
example of joint products with joint
costs. The decision whether and on
which platform to post an order will
20 For the fees related to ISE TOP Quote Feed and
Depth of Market, see supra notes 11 and 12.
21 For the fees related to NYSE Arca Book of
Options and Phlx TOPO Plus Orders, see supra
notes 13 and 14.
22 For the fees related to the CBOE market data
product, see supra note 15.
E:\FR\FM\27JNN1.SGM
27JNN1
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
38760
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 124 / Thursday, June 27, 2013 / Notices
depend on the attributes of the platform
where the order can be posted,
including the execution fees, data
quality and price and distribution of its
data products. Without the prospect of
a taking order seeing and reacting to a
posted order on a particular platform,
the posting of the order would
accomplish little. Without orders
entered and trades executed, exchange
data products cannot exist. Data
products are valuable to many end
Subscribers insofar as they provide
information that end Subscribers expect
will assist them in making trading
decisions.
The costs of producing market data
include not only the costs of the data
distribution infrastructure, but also the
costs of designing, maintaining, and
operating an exchange’s transaction
execution platform and the cost of
regulating the exchange to ensure its fair
operation and maintain investor
confidence. The total return that a
trading platform earns reflects the
revenues it receives from both products
and the joint costs it incurs. Moreover,
an exchange’s customers view the costs
of transaction executions and of data as
a unified cost of doing business with the
exchange. A broker-dealer will direct
orders to a particular exchange only if
the expected revenues from executing
trades on the exchange exceed net
transaction execution costs and the cost
of data that the broker-dealer chooses to
buy to support its trading decisions (or
those of its customers). The choice of
data products is, in turn, a product of
the value of the products in making
profitable trading decisions. If the cost
of the product exceeds its expected
value, the broker-dealer will choose not
to buy it. Moreover, as a broker-dealer
chooses to direct fewer orders to a
particular exchange, the value of the
product to that broker-dealer decreases,
for two reasons. First, the product will
contain less information, because
executions of the broker-dealer’s orders
will not be reflected in it. Second, and
perhaps more important, the product
will be less valuable to that brokerdealer because it does not provide
information about the venue to which it
is directing its orders. Data from the
competing venue to which the brokerdealer is directing orders will become
correspondingly more valuable.
‘‘No one disputes that competition for
order flow is fierce.’’ NetCoalition at 24.
However, the existence of fierce
competition for order flow implies a
high degree of price sensitivity on the
part of broker-dealers with order flow,
since they may readily reduce costs by
directing orders toward the lowest-cost
trading venues. A broker-dealer that
VerDate Mar<15>2010
18:12 Jun 26, 2013
Jkt 229001
shifted its order flow from one platform
to another in response to order
execution price differentials would both
reduce the value of that platform’s
market data and reduce its own need to
consume data from the disfavored
platform. Similarly, if a platform
increases its market data fees, the
change will affect the overall cost of
doing business with the platform, and
affected broker-dealers will assess
whether they can lower their trading
costs by directing orders elsewhere and
thereby lessening the need for the more
expensive data.
Analyzing the cost of market data
distribution in isolation from the cost of
all of the inputs supporting the creation
of market data will inevitably
underestimate the cost of the data. Thus,
because it is impossible to create data
without a fast, technologically robust,
and well-regulated execution system,
system costs and regulatory costs affect
the price of market data. It would be
equally misleading, however, to
attribute all of the exchange’s costs to
the market data portion of an exchange’s
joint product. Rather, all of the
exchange’s costs are incurred for the
unified purposes of attracting order
flow, executing and/or routing orders,
and generating and selling data about
market activity. The total return that an
exchange earns reflects the revenues it
receives from the joint products and the
total costs of the joint products.
Competition among trading platforms
can be expected to constrain the
aggregate return each platform earns
from the sale of its joint products, but
different platforms may choose from a
range of possible, and equally
reasonable, pricing strategies as the
means of recovering total costs. For
example, some platform may choose to
pay rebates to attract orders, charge
relatively low prices for market
information (or provide information free
of charge) and charge relatively high
prices for accessing posted liquidity.
Other platforms may choose a strategy
of paying lower rebates (or no rebates)
to attract orders, setting relatively high
prices for market information, and
setting relatively low prices for
accessing posted liquidity. In this
environment, there is no economic basis
for regulating maximum prices for one
of the joint products in an industry in
which suppliers face competitive
constraints with regard to the joint
offering. This would be akin to strictly
regulating the price that an automobile
manufacturer can charge for car sound
systems despite the existence of a highly
competitive market for cars and the
availability of after-market alternatives
to the manufacturer-supplied system.
PO 00000
Frm 00079
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
The market for market data products
is competitive and inherently
contestable because there is fierce
competition for the inputs necessary to
the creation of proprietary data and
strict pricing discipline for the
proprietary products themselves.
Numerous exchanges compete with
each other for listings, trades, and
market data itself, providing virtually
limitless opportunities for entrepreneurs
who wish to produce and distribute
their own market data. This proprietary
data is produced by each individual
exchange, as well as other entities, in a
vigorously competitive market.
Broker-dealers currently have
numerous alternative venues for their
order flow, including more than ten
SRO markets, as well as internalizing
broker-dealers and various forms of
alternative trading systems (‘‘ATSs’’),
including dark pools and electronic
communication networks (‘‘ECNs’’).
Each SRO market competes to produce
transaction reports via trade executions,
and two Financial Industry Regulatory
Authority, Inc. (‘‘FINRA’’) regulated
Trade Reporting Facilities (‘‘TRFs’’)
compete to attract internalized
transaction reports. Competitive markets
for order flow, executions, and
transaction reports provide pricing
discipline for the inputs of proprietary
data products.
The large number of SROs, TRFs,
broker-dealers, and ATSs that currently
produce proprietary data or are
currently capable of producing it
provides further pricing discipline for
proprietary data products. Each SRO,
TRF, ATS, and broker-dealer is
currently permitted to produce
proprietary data products, and many
currently do or have announced plans to
do so, including NASDAQ, NYSE,
NYSE Amex (now NYSE MKT),
NYSEArca, DirectEdge and BATS.
Any ATS or BD can combine with any
other ATS, broker-dealer, or multiple
ATSs or broker-dealers to produce joint
proprietary data products. Additionally,
order routers and market data vendors
can facilitate single or multiple brokerdealers’ production of proprietary data
products. The potential sources of
proprietary products are virtually
limitless.
The fact that proprietary data from
ATSs, broker-dealers, and vendors can
by-pass SROs is significant in two
respects. First, non-SROs can compete
directly with SROs for the production
and sale of proprietary data products as,
for example, BATS and Arca did before
registering as exchanges by publishing
Depth-of-Book data on the Internet.
Second, because a single order or
transaction report can appear in an SRO
E:\FR\FM\27JNN1.SGM
27JNN1
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 124 / Thursday, June 27, 2013 / Notices
proprietary product, a non-SRO
proprietary product, or both, the data
available in proprietary products is
exponentially greater than the actual
number of orders and transaction
reports that exist in the marketplace.
Market data vendors provide another
form of price discipline for proprietary
data products because they control the
primary means of access to end
Subscribers. Vendors impose price
restraints based upon their business
models. For example, vendors such as
Bloomberg and Thomson Reuters that
assess a surcharge on data they sell may
refuse to offer proprietary products that
end Subscribers will not purchase in
sufficient numbers. Internet portals,
such as Google, impose a discipline by
providing only data that will enable
them to attract ‘‘eyeballs’’ that
contribute to their advertising revenue.
Retail broker-dealers, such as Schwab
and Fidelity, offer their customers
proprietary data only if it promotes
trading and generates sufficient
commission revenue. Although the
business models may differ, these
vendors’ pricing discipline is the same:
they can simply refuse to purchase any
proprietary data product that fails to
provide sufficient value. BX and other
producers of proprietary data products
must understand and respond to these
varying business models and pricing
disciplines in order to market
proprietary data products successfully.
In addition to the competition and
price discipline described above, the
market for proprietary data products is
also highly contestable because market
entry is rapid, inexpensive, and
profitable. The history of electronic
trading is replete with examples of
entrants that swiftly grew into some of
the largest electronic trading platforms
and proprietary data producers:
Archipelago, Bloomberg Tradebook,
Island, RediBook, Attain, TracECN,
BATS and Direct Edge. A proliferation
of dark pools and other ATSs operate
profitably with fragmentary shares of
consolidated market volume.
Regulation NMS, by deregulating the
market for proprietary data, has
increased the contestability of that
market. While broker-dealers have
previously published their proprietary
data individually, Regulation NMS
encourages market data vendors and
broker-dealers to produce proprietary
products cooperatively in a manner
never before possible. Multiple market
data vendors already have the capability
to aggregate data and disseminate it on
a profitable scale, including Bloomberg,
and Thomson Reuters.
Competition among platforms has
driven BX continually to improve its
VerDate Mar<15>2010
18:12 Jun 26, 2013
Jkt 229001
platform data offerings and to cater to
customers’ data needs. For example, BX
has developed and maintained multiple
delivery mechanisms (IP, multi-cast,
and compression) that enable customers
to receive data in the form and manner
they prefer and at the lowest cost to
them. BX has created new products like
BX Depth, because offering data in
multiple formatting allows BX to better
fit customer needs. BX offers data via
multiple extranet and
telecommunication providers such as
Verizon, BT Radianz, and Savvis, among
others, thereby helping to reduce
network and total cost for its data
products. BX has an online
administrative system to provide
customers transparency into their
datafeed requests and streamline data
usage reporting. BX is also
implementing an Enterprise License
option to reduce the administrative
burden and costs to firms that purchase
market data.
Despite these enhancements and ever
increasing message traffic, BX’s fees for
market data have remained flat. The
same holds true for execution services;
despite numerous enhancements to BX’s
trading platform, absolute and relative
trading costs have declined. Platform
competition has intensified as new
entrants have emerged, constraining
prices for both executions and for data.
The vigor of competition for options
data is significant and the Exchange
believes that this proposal itself clearly
evidences such competition. The
Exchange has witnessed competitors
creating new products and innovative
pricing in this space over the course of
the past year. BX continues to see firms
challenge its pricing on the basis of the
Exchange’s explicit fees being higher
than the zero-priced fees from other
competitors such as BATS. In all cases,
firms make decisions on how much and
what types of data to consume on the
basis of the total cost of interacting with
BX or other exchanges. Of course, the
explicit data fees are but one factor in
a total platform analysis. Some
competitors have lower transactions fees
and higher data fees, and others are vice
versa. The market for the proposed data
is highly competitive and continually
evolves as products develop and
change.
C. Self-Regulatory Organization’s
Statement on Comments on the
Proposed Rule Change Received From
Members, Participants or Others
No written comments were either
solicited or received.
PO 00000
Frm 00080
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
38761
III. Date of Effectiveness of the
Proposed Rule Change and Timing for
Commission Action
The foregoing rule change has become
effective pursuant to Section 19(b)(3)(A)
of the Act 23 and paragraph (f) of Rule
19b–4 thereunder.24
At any time within 60 days of the
filing of the proposed rule change, the
Commission summarily may
temporarily suspend such rule change if
it appears to the Commission that such
action is necessary or appropriate in the
public interest, for the protection of
investors, or otherwise in furtherance of
the purposes of the Act.
IV. Solicitation of Comments
Interested persons are invited to
submit written data, views, and
arguments concerning the foregoing,
including whether the proposed rule
change is consistent with the Act.
Comments may be submitted by any of
the following methods:
Electronic Comments
• Use the Commission’s Internet
comment form (https://www.sec.gov/
rules/sro.shtml); or
• Send an email to rulecomments@sec.gov. Please include File
Number SR–BX–2013–040 on the
subject line.
Paper Comments
• Send paper comments in triplicate
to Elizabeth M. Murphy, Secretary,
Securities and Exchange Commission,
100 F Street NE., Washington, DC
20549–1090.
All submissions should refer to File
Number SR–BX–2013–040. This file
number should be included on the
subject line if email is used.
To help the Commission process and
review your comments more efficiently,
please use only one method. The
Commission will post all comments on
the Commission’s Internet Web site
(https://www.sec.gov/rules/sro.shtml).
Copies of the submission, all subsequent
amendments, all written statements
with respect to the proposed rule
change that are filed with the
Commission, and all written
communications relating to the
proposed rule change between the
Commission and any person, other than
those that may be withheld from the
public in accordance with the
provisions of 5 U.S.C. 552, will be
available for Web site viewing and
printing in the Commission’s Public
Reference Room, 100 F Street NE.,
Washington, DC 20549, on official
23 15
24 17
E:\FR\FM\27JNN1.SGM
U.S.C. 78s(b)(3)(A).
CFR 240.19b–4(f).
27JNN1
38762
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 124 / Thursday, June 27, 2013 / Notices
business days between the hours of
10:00 a.m. and 3:00 p.m. Copies of such
filing also will be available for
inspection and copying at the principal
offices of BX. All comments received
will be posted without change; the
Commission does not edit personal
identifying information from
submissions. You should submit only
information that you wish to make
available publicly. All submissions
should refer to File Number SR–SR–BX–
2013–040, and should be submitted on
or before July 18, 2013.
For the Commission, by the Division of
Trading and Markets, pursuant to delegated
authority.25
Jill M. Peterson,
Assistant Secretary.
[FR Doc. 2013–15373 Filed 6–26–13; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 8011–01–P
SECURITIES AND EXCHANGE
COMMISSION
[Release No. 34–69814; File No. SR–
NYSEMKT–2013–53]
Self-Regulatory Organizations; NYSE
MKT LLC; Notice of Filing and
Immediate Effectiveness of Proposed
Rule Change Amending NYSE MKT
Rule 500—Equities To Extend the
Operation of the Pilot Program That
Allows Nasdaq Stock Market Securities
To Be Traded on the Exchange
Pursuant to a Grant of Unlisted
Trading Privileges Until the Earlier of
Securities and Exchange Commission
Approval To Make Such Pilot
Permanent or January 31, 2014
June 20, 2013.
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
Pursuant to Section 19(b)(1) 1 of the
Securities Exchange Act of 1934 (the
‘‘Act’’) 2 and Rule 19b–4 thereunder,3
notice is hereby given that on June 17,
2013, NYSE MKT LLC (‘‘NYSE MKT’’ or
‘‘Exchange’’) filed with the Securities
and Exchange Commission
(‘‘Commission’’) the proposed rule
change as described in Items I and II
below, which Items have been prepared
by the Exchange. The Commission is
publishing this notice to solicit
comments on the proposed rule change
from interested persons.
I. Self-Regulatory Organization’s
Statement of the Terms of Substance of
the Proposed Rule Change
The Exchange proposes to proposes to
amend NYSE MKT Rule 500—Equities
to extend the operation of the pilot
25 17
CFR 200.30–3(a)(12).
U.S.C. 78s(b)(1).
2 15 U.S.C. 78a.
3 17 CFR 240.19b–4.
1 15
VerDate Mar<15>2010
18:12 Jun 26, 2013
Jkt 229001
program that allows Nasdaq Stock
Market (‘‘Nasdaq’’) securities to be
traded on the Exchange pursuant to a
grant of unlisted trading privileges. The
pilot is currently scheduled to expire on
July 31, 2013; the Exchange proposes to
extend it until the earlier of Securities
and Exchange Commission
(‘‘Commission’’) approval to make such
pilot permanent or January 31, 2014.
The text of the proposed rule change is
available on the Exchange’s Web site at
www.nyse.com, at the principal office of
the Exchange, and at the Commission’s
Public Reference Room.
II. Self-Regulatory Organization’s
Statement of the Purpose of, and
Statutory Basis for, the Proposed Rule
Change
In its filing with the Commission, the
self-regulatory organization included
statements concerning the purpose of,
and basis for, the proposed rule change
and discussed any comments it received
on the proposed rule change. The text
of those statements may be examined at
the places specified in Item IV below.
The Exchange has prepared summaries,
set forth in sections A, B, and C below,
of the most significant parts of such
statements.
A. Self-Regulatory Organization’s
Statement of the Purpose of, and
Statutory Basis for, the Proposed Rule
Change
1. Purpose
NYSE MKT Rules 500–525—Equities,
as a pilot program, govern the trading of
any Nasdaq-listed security on the
Exchange pursuant to unlisted trading
privileges (‘‘UTP Pilot Program’’).4 The
Exchange hereby seeks to extend the
operation of the UTP Pilot Program,
currently scheduled to expire on July
31, 2013, until the earlier of
Commission approval to make such
pilot permanent or January 31, 2014.
The UTP Pilot Program includes any
security listed on Nasdaq that (i) is
designated as an ‘‘eligible security’’
under the Joint Self-Regulatory
Organization Plan Governing the
Collection, Consolidation and
Dissemination of Quotation and
4 See Securities Exchange Act Release No. 62479
(July 9, 2010), 75 FR 41264 (July 15, 2010) (SR–
NYSEAmex–2010–31). See also Securities
Exchange Act Release Nos. 62857 (September 7,
2010), 75 FR 55837 (September 14, 2010) (SR–
NYSEAmex–2010–89); 63601 (December 22, 2010),
75 FR 82117 (December 29, 2010) (SR–NYSEAmex–
2010–124); 64746 (June 24, 2011), 76 FR 38446
(June 30, 2011) (SR–NYSEAmex–2011–45); 66040
(December 23, 2011), 76 FR 82324 (December 30,
2011) (SR–NYSEAmex–2011–104); 67497 (July 25,
2012), 77 FR 45404 (July 31, 2012) (SR–NYSEMKT–
2012–25); and 68561 (January 2, 2013), 78 FR 1290
(January 8, 2013) (SR–NYSEMKT–2012–86).
PO 00000
Frm 00081
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
Transaction Information for NasdaqListed Securities Traded on Exchanges
on an Unlisted Trading Privilege Basis,
as amended (‘‘UTP Plan’’),5 and (ii) has
been admitted to dealings on the
Exchange pursuant to a grant of unlisted
trading privileges in accordance with
Section 12(f) of the Securities Exchange
Act of 1934, as amended (the ‘‘Act’’),6
(collectively, ‘‘Nasdaq Securities’’).7
The Exchange notes that its New
Market Model Pilot (‘‘NMM Pilot’’),
which, among other things, eliminated
the function of specialists on the
Exchange and created a new category of
market participant, the Designated
Market Maker (‘‘DMM’’),8 is also
scheduled to end on July 31, 2013.9 The
timing of the operation of the UTP Pilot
Program was designed to correspond to
that of the NMM Pilot. In approving the
UTP Pilot Program, the Commission
acknowledged that the rules relating to
DMM benefits and duties in trading
Nasdaq Securities on the Exchange
pursuant to the UTP Pilot Program are
consistent with the Act 10 and noted the
similarity to the NMM Pilot, particularly
with respect to DMM obligations and
benefits.11 Furthermore, the UTP Pilot
Program rules pertaining to the
5 See Securities Exchange Act Release No. 58863
(October 27, 2008), 73 FR 65417 (November 3, 2008)
(File No. S7–24–89). The Exchange’s predecessor,
the American Stock Exchange LLC, joined the UTP
Plan in 2001. See Securities Exchange Act Release
No. 55647 (April 19, 2007), 72 FR 20891 (April 26,
2007) (File No. S7–24–89). In March 2009, the
Exchange changed its name to NYSE Amex LLC,
and, in May 2012, the Exchange subsequently
changed its name to NYSE MKT LLC. See Securities
Exchange Act Release Nos. 59575 (March 13, 2009),
74 FR 11803 (March 19, 2009) (SR–NYSEALTR–
2009–24) and 67037 (May 21, 2012), 77 FR 31415
(May 25, 2012) (SR–NYSEAmex–2012–32).
6 15 U.S.C. 78l.
7 ‘‘Nasdaq Securities’’ is included within the
definition of ‘‘security’’ as that term is used in the
NYSE MKT Equities Rules. See NYSE MKT Rule
3—Equities. In accordance with this definition,
Nasdaq Securities are admitted to dealings on the
Exchange on an ‘‘issued,’’ ‘‘when issued,’’ or ‘‘when
distributed’’ basis. See NYSE MKT Rule 501—
Equities.
8 See NYSE MKT Rule 103—Equities.
9 See Securities Exchange Act Release No. 60758
(October 1, 2009), 74 FR 51639 (October 7, 2009)
(SR–NYSEAmex–2009–65). See also Securities
Exchange Act Release Nos. 61030 (November 19,
2009), 74 FR 62365 (November 27, 2009) (SR–
NYSEAmex–2009–83); 61725 (March 17, 2010), 75
FR 14223 (March 24, 2010) (SR–NYSEAmex–2010–
28); 62820 (September 1, 2010), 75 FR 54935
(September 9, 2010) (SR–NYSEAmex–2010–86);
63615 (December 29, 2010), 76 FR 611 (January 5,
2011) (SR–NYSEAmex–2010–123); 64773 (June 29,
2011), 76 FR 39453 (July 6, 2011) (SR–NYSEAmex–
2011–43); 66042 (December 23, 2011), 76 FR 82326
(December 30, 2011) (SR–NYSEAmex–2011–102);
67495 (July 25, 2012), 77 FR 45406 (July 31, 2012)
(SR–NYSEMKT–2012–21); and 68559 (January 2,
2013), 78 FR 1286 (January 8, 2013) (SR–
NYSEMKT–2012–84).
10 15 U.S.C. 78.
11 See SR–NYSEAmex–2010–31, supra note 4, at
41271.
E:\FR\FM\27JNN1.SGM
27JNN1
Agencies
[Federal Register Volume 78, Number 124 (Thursday, June 27, 2013)]
[Notices]
[Pages 38757-38762]
From the Federal Register Online via the Government Printing Office [www.gpo.gov]
[FR Doc No: 2013-15373]
[[Page 38757]]
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
SECURITIES AND EXCHANGE COMMISSION
[Release No. 34-69821; File No. SR-BX-2013-040]
Self-Regulatory Organizations; NASDAQ OMX BX, Inc.; Notice of
Filing and Immediate Effectiveness of Proposed Rule Change To Amend
Section 4 of Chapter XV of the BX Options Rules
June 21, 2013.
Pursuant to Section 19(b)(1) of the Securities Exchange Act of 1934
(``Act'') \1\, and Rule 19b-4 thereunder,\2\ notice is hereby given
that on June 11, 2013, NASDAQ OMX BX, Inc. (``BX'' or ``Exchange'')
filed with the Securities and Exchange Commission (``SEC'' or
``Commission'') the proposed rule change as described in Items I, II,
and III below, which Items have been prepared by the Exchange. The
Commission is publishing this notice to solicit comments on the
proposed rule change from interested persons.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1\ 15 U.S.C. 78s(b)(1).
\2\ 17 CFR 240.19b-4.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
I. Self-Regulatory Organization's Statement of the Terms of Substance
of the Proposed Rule Change
The Exchange proposes to amend Section 4 of Chapter XV of the BX
Options Rules setting forth the fees for options market data known as
BX Top of Market Options (``BX Top'') and BX Depth of Market Options
(``BX Depth''). The text of the proposed rule change is also available
on the Exchange's Web site at https://nasdaqomxbx.cchwallstreet.com, at
the principal office of the Exchange, and at the Commission's Public
Reference Room.
II. Self-Regulatory Organization's Statement of the Purpose of, and
Statutory Basis for, the Proposed Rule Change
In its filing with the Commission, the Exchange included statements
concerning the purpose of and basis for the proposed rule change and
discussed any comments it received on the proposed rule change. The
text of these statements may be examined at the places specified in
Item IV below. The Exchange has prepared summaries, set forth in
sections A, B, and C below, of the most significant aspects of such
statements.
A. Self-Regulatory Organization's Statement of the Purpose of, and
Statutory Basis for, the Proposed Rule Change
1. Purpose
The Exchange proposes to amend Section 4 of Chapter XV to set forth
the fees for options market data already distributed as BX Top and BX
Depth. The Exchange has been offering the BX Top and BX Depth options
market data free of charge for almost a year since the launch of the BX
Options Market. The Exchange now proposes to institute fees for
recipients of BX Top and BX Depth data, with a free trial offer for
certain data recipients.
BX Depth is currently described in the Exchange's option rules at
subsection (a)(3)(A) of Chapter VI, Section 1 as a data package that
includes quotation information for individual orders on the BX book,
last sale information for trades executed on BX, and Order Imbalance
Information as set forth in BX Rules Chapter VI, Section 8. Members use
BX Depth to ``build'' their view of the BX book by adding individual
orders that appear in the data, and subtracting individual orders that
are executed.
BX Top is currently described in subsection (a)(3)(B) of Chapter
VI, Section 1 as a data package that includes the BX Best Bid and Offer
(``BX BBO'') and last sale information for trades executed on BX. The
BX BBO and last sale information are identical to the information that
BX sends the Options Price Regulatory Authority (``OPRA'') and which
OPRA disseminates via the consolidated data feed for options.
BX proposes to set fees for BX Top and BX Depth data that use
elements of the current fee structure for recipients of BX TotalView
and BX BBO,\3\ which are equities market data products similar to BX
Top and BX Depth. First, the Exchange proposes to charge monthly fees
for firms that are Distributors of BX Top and BX Depth data. Proposed
Section 4(b) of Chapter XV states that a ``Distributor'' of BX options
market data is any entity that receives a feed or data file of BX data
directly from BX or indirectly through another entity and then
distributes the data either internally (within that entity) or
externally (outside that entity). Proposed subsection 4(b) also states
that all Distributors would be required to execute a Distributor
agreement with the Exchange. The amount of the monthly fees would
depend on whether a Distributor is an ``Internal Distributor'' or
``External Distributor.'' \4\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\3\ See BX Rules 7023 and 7047.
\4\ Thus, a Distributor may pay either ``Internal Distributor''
or ``External Distributor'' fees.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
An Internal Distributor is a firm that is permitted by agreement
with the Exchange to provide BX Top and BX Depth data to internal
Subscribers (i.e., users within their own organization). Under the
proposal, Distributors that only use the BX data internally would be
charged monthly fee of $1,500 per firm.
An External Distributor is a firm that is permitted by agreement
with the Exchange to provide BX Top and BX Depth data to both internal
Subscribers and to external Subscribers (i.e., users outside of their
own organization). Distributors provide BX data externally would be
charged a monthly fee of $2,000 per firm. The fee paid by an External
Distributor includes the Internal Distributor Fee. The fee paid by an
Internal Distributor or an External Distributor would allow access to
both the BX Top and BX Depth data feeds.
The Exchange also proposes to assess Subscriber fees for BX Top and
BX Depth data on a Per Subscriber basis.\5\ These fees would vary based
on whether they are for Professional Subscribers or Non-Professional
Subscribers. Proposed Section 4(f) states that the term ``Non-
Professional'' shall have the same meaning as in BX Rule 7023(b)(2).
Rule 7023(b)(2) defines a ``Non-Professional'' as a natural person who
is neither: (A) Registered or qualified in any capacity with the
Commission, the Commodities Futures Trading Commission, any state
securities agency, any securities exchange or association, or any
commodities or futures contract market or association; (B) engaged as
an ``investment adviser'' as that term is defined in Section 201(11) of
the Investment Advisors Act of 1940 (whether or not registered or
qualified under that Act); nor (C) employed by a bank or other
organization exempt from registration under federal or state securities
laws to perform functions that would require registration or
qualification if such functions were performed for an organization not
so exempt.\6\ A Professional Subscriber is any recipient that is not a
Non-Professional.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\5\ While the Subscriber fees would be paid by firms (Internal
Distributors and External Distributors), some portion of the fees
may be passed through to Subscribers inside or outside the firms
(that is, to internal or external Subscribers).
\6\ The Exchange believes that Non-Professional Subscribers of
market data, in contrast to Professional data Subscribers and
Distributors, often tend to be individual consumers, smaller retail
investors, and public customers.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
[[Page 38758]]
For BX Top data, the proposed Subscriber fees are $5 per
Professional Subscriber; and $1 per Non-Professional Subscriber. For BX
Depth data, the proposed fees are $10 per Professional Subscriber; and
$1 per Non-Professional Subscriber.
The Exchange notes that for many years, exchanges have engaged in
and the Commission has accepted the practice of price differentiation,
both in the context of market data as well as in the context of
executions. With respect to market data, NASDAQ and NYSE Euronext
(``NYSE'') in their capacities as network processors and exchanges have
differentiated in pricing between Professional and Non-Professional
market data Subscriber, often charging Professionals many times more
than Non-Professionals for using the same data. For example, NASDAQ
currently charges Non-Professionals $15 per terminal for its NASDAQ
Depth Data via a standalone terminal, while Professional Subscribers
pay roughly five times the Non-Professional rate.\7\ This reflects the
value of the service to various constituencies (i.e., lower prices are
charged to consumers with more elastic demand) and allows both types of
investors to contribute to the high fixed costs of operating an
exchange platform. The Exchange believes that this differentiation for
Professional and Non-Professional data usage, as the differentiation
for Professional and Non-Professional Subscribers proposed in this
filing, is completely consistent with past Commission precedent and
economic theory.\8\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\7\ See BX [sic] Rule 7023.
\8\ In economic terms, charging lower fees to non-professional
consumers increases overall economic welfare by increasing output--
in this case, providing more data to more investors--and avoids two
equally undesirable alternatives: (i) Requiring the firm to charge
uniformly high prices that constrict demand, or (ii) insisting on
uniformly low prices at marginal cost (potentially zero or close to
zero) that do not allow the firm to cover its fixed costs and
thereby lead to bankruptcy.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The Exchange also proposes to assess a monthly non-display
enterprise license fee. Proposed Section 4(c) of Chapter XV states that
an ``Enterprise License'' entitles a Distributor to provide BX Top and
BX Depth market data pursuant to this rule to an unlimited number of
non-display devices \9\ internally (within the firm) without any
additional Subscriber fees associated with these non-display devices.
Under the proposal, Distributors of BX Top and BX Depth data, if they
choose to subscribe to a non-display enterprise license, would be
charged a monthly enterprise license fee or $2,500.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\9\ Non-display devices do not graphically show (display) BX Top
and BX Depth market data but instead use the data for performance of
analytic or calculative functions (e.g. algorithms).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The non-display enterprise license is in addition to the Internal
or External Distributor fees. Thus, a firm that has a non-display
enterprise license could pay an Internal Distributor fee and the
Enterprise License fee and distribute data to limitless number of non-
display devices (devices within the firm) pursuant to the license
without incurring further fees for each internal device. However, the
enterprise license does not allow external distribution without
incurring an External Distributor fee and external Subscriber fees, if
applicable under the circumstances.
Finally, the Exchange proposes a 30-Day Free Trial Offer in
proposed subsection (g) of Section 4.\10\ In particular, the 30-day
waiver of the Subscriber fees for BX options market data pursuant to
the rule extends to all new individual (non-firm) Subscribers. This fee
waiver period will be applied on a rolling basis, determined by the
date on which a new individual (non-distributor or firm) is first
entitled by a Distributor to receive access to BX options market data.
Subsection (g) provides that a Distributor may only provide this waiver
to a specific Subscriber at one time.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\10\ The Exchange also offers a 30-day free trial for BX
TotalView. See BX Rule 7023.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The Exchange notes that the categories of BX Top and BX Depth
market data and fees compare favorably with similar products offered by
other markets such as International Stock Exchange (``ISE''), NYSE,
NASDAQ OMX PHLX (``Phlx''), and Chicago Board Options Exchange
(``CBOE''). For example, ISE offers market data products that are
similar to BX Top: a data feed that shows the top of the market
entitled TOP Quote Feed,\11\ and a data feed that shows the top five
price levels entitled Depth of Market.\12\ NYSE offers a market data
product for Arca and Amex that is similar to BX Top and BX Depth: a
feed that shows top of book, last sale, and depth of quote and is
entitled NYSE Arca Book for Options.\13\ Phlx offers a market data feed
entitled TOPO that is similar to BX Top and shows orders and quotes at
the top of the market, as well as trades; and a Phlx Depth feed that is
similar to BX Depth and shows the data in the TOPO data feed as well as
the depth of orders. \14\ A subsidiary of CBOE for which CBOE charges
fees offers a market data feed that is similar to BX Top and shows BBO,
last sale, and top of book data.\15\ And BATS offers Multicast PITCH,
which is their depth of market and last sale feed similar to BX
Depth.\16\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\11\ The ISE TOP Quote Feed has a monthly base access fee of
$3,000 applicable to professionals and non-professionals plus a $20
variable device fee for professionals and a no device fee for
internal use professionals; or a flat fixed enterprise fee of $5,000
for unlimited internal/external use and a $4,000 fee for unlimited
internal use. The Exchange notes that the monthly fees for the ISE
TOP Quote Feed are higher than those proposed in this filing.
\12\ The ISE Depth of Market Feed has a monthly base access fee
of $5,000 applicable to professionals and non-professionals plus a
$50 variable device fee for professionals and a $5 per device fee
for external distribution non-professionals; or a flat fixed
enterprise fee of $7,500 for unlimited internal use, and $10,000 for
unlimited internal/external use. The Exchange notes that the monthly
fees for ISE Depth of Market are higher than those proposed in this
filing for a more robust product.
\13\ The fee for NYSE Arca Book for Options is $3,000 per month
for direct or indirect access, $2,000 for external redistribution;
and a $50 per user professional user fee and $1 per user Non-
professional user fee.
\14\ TOPO Plus Orders has a monthly fee of $4,000 for internal
distributors or $5,000 for external distributors plus a monthly fee
of $1 per Non-Professional Subscribers and $20 for Professional
Subscribers. The Exchange notes that the monthly fees for TOPO Plus
Orders are higher than those proposed in this filing. See Securities
Exchange Act Release No. 62194 (May 28, 2010), 75 FR 31830 (June 4,
2010) (SR-Phlx-2010-48) (order approving proposal related to TOPO
Plus Orders market data fees).
\15\ The subsidiary is identified as Market Data Express, LLC
(``MDX'') by CBOE, which indicates that the feed will also provide
data regarding contingency orders and complex strategies. The
monthly fee charged by CBOE for the data is $3,500 plus a $25 per
user or device fee. See Securities Exchange Act Release No. 63997
(March 1, 2011), 76 FR 12388 (March 7, 2011) (SR-CBOE-2011-014)
(notice of filing and immediate effectiveness). In the filing, CBOE
specifically references as similar products the Phlx TOPO Plus
Orders feed and the ISE Depth of Market Feed.
\16\ BATS offers Multicast PITCH without charge ostensibly to
attract order flow to that exchange.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The Exchange believes that the continued availability of BX Top and
BX Depth data feeds enhances transparency, fosters competition among
orders and markets, and enables buyers and sellers to obtain better
prices.
2. Statutory Basis
BX believes that the proposed rule change is consistent with the
provisions of Section 6 of the Act,\17\ in general, and with Section
6(b)(4) of the Act,\18\ in particular, in that it provides an equitable
allocation of reasonable fees among recipients of BX data. In adopting
Regulation NMS, the Commission granted self-regulatory organizations
and broker-dealers increased authority and flexibility to offer new and
unique market data to the public. It was believed that this authority
would expand the amount of data available to consumers, and also
[[Page 38759]]
spur innovation and competition for the provision of market data.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\17\ 15 U.S.C. 78f.
\18\ 15 U.S.C. 78f(b)(4).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The Commission concluded that Regulation NMS--by deregulating the
market in proprietary data--would itself further the Act's goals of
facilitating efficiency and competition:
[E]fficiency is promoted when broker-dealers who do not need the
data beyond the prices, sizes, market center identifications of the
NBBO and consolidated last sale information are not required to
receive (and pay for) such data. The Commission also believes that
efficiency is promoted when broker-dealers may choose to receive
(and pay for) additional market data based on their own internal
analysis of the need for such data.\19\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\19\ Securities Exchange Act Release No. 51808 (June 9, 2005),
70 FR 37496 (June 29, 2005).
By removing ``unnecessary regulatory restrictions'' on the ability of
exchanges to sell their own data, Regulation NMS advanced the goals of
the Act and the principles reflected in its legislative history. If the
free market should determine whether proprietary data is sold to
broker-dealers at all, it follows that the price at which such data is
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
sold should be set by the market as well.
On July 21, 2010, President Barack Obama signed into law H.R. 4173,
the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act of 2010
(``Dodd-Frank Act''), which amended Section 19 of the Act. Among other
things, Section 916 of the Dodd-Frank Act amended paragraph (A) of
Section 19(b)(3) of the Act by inserting the phrase ``on any person,
whether or not the person is a member of the self-regulatory
organization'' after ``due, fee or other charge imposed by the self-
regulatory organization.'' As a result, all SRO rule proposals
establishing or changing dues, fees, or other charges are immediately
effective upon filing regardless of whether such dues, fees, or other
charges are imposed on members of the SRO, non-members, or both.
Section 916 further amended paragraph (C) of Section 19(b)(3) of the
Exchange Act to read, in pertinent part, ``At any time within the 60-
day period beginning on the date of filing of such a proposed rule
change in accordance with the provisions of paragraph (1) [of Section
19(b)], the Commission summarily may temporarily suspend the change in
the rules of the self-regulatory organization made thereby, if it
appears to the Commission that such action is necessary or appropriate
in the public interest, for the protection of investors, or otherwise
in furtherance of the purposes of this title. If the Commission takes
such action, the Commission shall institute proceedings under paragraph
(2)(B) [of Section 19(b)] to determine whether the proposed rule should
be approved or disapproved.''
The decision of the United States Court of Appeals for the District
of Columbia Circuit in NetCoalition v. SEC, No. 09-1042 (D.C. Cir.
2010), although reviewing a Commission decision made prior to the
effective date of the Dodd-Frank Act, upheld the Commission's reliance
upon competitive markets to set reasonable and equitably allocated fees
for market data. ``In fact, the legislative history indicates that the
Congress intended that the market system evolve through the interplay
of competitive forces as unnecessary regulatory restrictions are
removed' and that the SEC wield its regulatory power in those
situations where competition may not be sufficient, `such as in the
creation of a consolidated transactional reporting system.' ''
NetCoalition, at 15 (quoting H.R. Rep. No. 94-229, at 92 (1975), as
reprinted in 1975 U.S.C.C.A.N. 321, 323).
BX believes that the proposed fees are fair and equitable, and not
unreasonably discriminatory. The proposed fees are based on pricing
conventions and distinctions that currently exist in the fee schedules
of other exchanges, including NASDAQ and PHLX. These distinctions (e.g.
Distributor versus Subscriber, Professional versus Non-Professional,
internal versus external distribution, controlled versus uncontrolled
datafeed) are each based on principles of fairness and equity that have
helped for many years to maintain fair, equitable, and not unreasonably
discriminatory fees, and that apply with equal or greater force to the
current proposal. BX believes that the BX Top and BX Depth offerings is
equitable in that it provides an opportunity for all Distributors and
Subscribers, Professional and Non-Professional, to identical data
without unfairly discriminating against any.
Thus, if BX has calculated improperly and the market deems the
proposed fees to be unfair, inequitable, or unreasonably
discriminatory, firms can diminish or discontinue the use of their data
because the proposed fees are entirely optional to all parties. Firms
are not required to choose to purchase BX Top or BX Depth or to utilize
any specific pricing alternative. BX is not required to make BX Top or
BX Depth available or to offer specific pricing alternatives for
potential purchases. BX can discontinue offering a pricing alternative
(as it has in the past) and firms can discontinue their use at any time
and for any reason (as they often do), including due to their
assessment of the reasonableness of fees charged. BX continues to
establish and revise pricing policies aimed at increasing fairness and
equitable allocation of fees among Subscribers.
Competitive products similar to BX Top or BX Depth are, as
previously discussed, offered by other exchanges, albeit sometimes at
higher prices. ISE offers two data products similar to BX Top that are
called TOP Quote Feed and Depth of Market and have fees higher than
those proposed in this filing.\20\ NYSE offers a market data product
similar to BX Top or BX Depth called NYSE Arca Book of Options that has
market data for NYSE Arca and NYSE Amex. Phlx offers a market data
product that is similar to ITTO.\21\ CBOE offers a market data product
that is similar to BX Top.\22\ BATS offers a market data product
similar to BX Depth. Moreover, the Exchange notes that, as a substitute
for exchange data, consolidated market data (e.g. last sale, NBBO,
current quotes) are also available from securities information
processors such as OPRA.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\20\ For the fees related to ISE TOP Quote Feed and Depth of
Market, see supra notes 11 and 12.
\21\ For the fees related to NYSE Arca Book of Options and Phlx
TOPO Plus Orders, see supra notes 13 and 14.
\22\ For the fees related to the CBOE market data product, see
supra note 15.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
B. Self-Regulatory Organization's Statement on Burden on Competition
BX does not believe that the proposed rule change will result in
any burden on competition that is not necessary or appropriate in
furtherance of the purposes of the Act, as amended. Notwithstanding its
determination that the Commission may rely upon competition to
establish fair and equitably allocated fees for market data, the
NetCoalition court found that the Commission had not, in that case,
compiled a record that adequately supported its conclusion that the
market for the data at issue in the case was competitive. BX believes
that a record may readily be established to demonstrate the competitive
nature of the market in question.
The proposal is, as described below, pro-competitive. There is
intense competition between trading platforms that provide transaction
execution and routing services and proprietary data products.
Transaction execution and proprietary data products are complementary
in that market data is both an input and a byproduct of the execution
service. In fact, market data and trade execution are a paradigmatic
example of joint products with joint costs. The decision whether and on
which platform to post an order will
[[Page 38760]]
depend on the attributes of the platform where the order can be posted,
including the execution fees, data quality and price and distribution
of its data products. Without the prospect of a taking order seeing and
reacting to a posted order on a particular platform, the posting of the
order would accomplish little. Without orders entered and trades
executed, exchange data products cannot exist. Data products are
valuable to many end Subscribers insofar as they provide information
that end Subscribers expect will assist them in making trading
decisions.
The costs of producing market data include not only the costs of
the data distribution infrastructure, but also the costs of designing,
maintaining, and operating an exchange's transaction execution platform
and the cost of regulating the exchange to ensure its fair operation
and maintain investor confidence. The total return that a trading
platform earns reflects the revenues it receives from both products and
the joint costs it incurs. Moreover, an exchange's customers view the
costs of transaction executions and of data as a unified cost of doing
business with the exchange. A broker-dealer will direct orders to a
particular exchange only if the expected revenues from executing trades
on the exchange exceed net transaction execution costs and the cost of
data that the broker-dealer chooses to buy to support its trading
decisions (or those of its customers). The choice of data products is,
in turn, a product of the value of the products in making profitable
trading decisions. If the cost of the product exceeds its expected
value, the broker-dealer will choose not to buy it. Moreover, as a
broker-dealer chooses to direct fewer orders to a particular exchange,
the value of the product to that broker-dealer decreases, for two
reasons. First, the product will contain less information, because
executions of the broker-dealer's orders will not be reflected in it.
Second, and perhaps more important, the product will be less valuable
to that broker-dealer because it does not provide information about the
venue to which it is directing its orders. Data from the competing
venue to which the broker-dealer is directing orders will become
correspondingly more valuable.
``No one disputes that competition for order flow is fierce.''
NetCoalition at 24. However, the existence of fierce competition for
order flow implies a high degree of price sensitivity on the part of
broker-dealers with order flow, since they may readily reduce costs by
directing orders toward the lowest-cost trading venues. A broker-dealer
that shifted its order flow from one platform to another in response to
order execution price differentials would both reduce the value of that
platform's market data and reduce its own need to consume data from the
disfavored platform. Similarly, if a platform increases its market data
fees, the change will affect the overall cost of doing business with
the platform, and affected broker-dealers will assess whether they can
lower their trading costs by directing orders elsewhere and thereby
lessening the need for the more expensive data.
Analyzing the cost of market data distribution in isolation from
the cost of all of the inputs supporting the creation of market data
will inevitably underestimate the cost of the data. Thus, because it is
impossible to create data without a fast, technologically robust, and
well-regulated execution system, system costs and regulatory costs
affect the price of market data. It would be equally misleading,
however, to attribute all of the exchange's costs to the market data
portion of an exchange's joint product. Rather, all of the exchange's
costs are incurred for the unified purposes of attracting order flow,
executing and/or routing orders, and generating and selling data about
market activity. The total return that an exchange earns reflects the
revenues it receives from the joint products and the total costs of the
joint products.
Competition among trading platforms can be expected to constrain
the aggregate return each platform earns from the sale of its joint
products, but different platforms may choose from a range of possible,
and equally reasonable, pricing strategies as the means of recovering
total costs. For example, some platform may choose to pay rebates to
attract orders, charge relatively low prices for market information (or
provide information free of charge) and charge relatively high prices
for accessing posted liquidity. Other platforms may choose a strategy
of paying lower rebates (or no rebates) to attract orders, setting
relatively high prices for market information, and setting relatively
low prices for accessing posted liquidity. In this environment, there
is no economic basis for regulating maximum prices for one of the joint
products in an industry in which suppliers face competitive constraints
with regard to the joint offering. This would be akin to strictly
regulating the price that an automobile manufacturer can charge for car
sound systems despite the existence of a highly competitive market for
cars and the availability of after-market alternatives to the
manufacturer-supplied system.
The market for market data products is competitive and inherently
contestable because there is fierce competition for the inputs
necessary to the creation of proprietary data and strict pricing
discipline for the proprietary products themselves. Numerous exchanges
compete with each other for listings, trades, and market data itself,
providing virtually limitless opportunities for entrepreneurs who wish
to produce and distribute their own market data. This proprietary data
is produced by each individual exchange, as well as other entities, in
a vigorously competitive market.
Broker-dealers currently have numerous alternative venues for their
order flow, including more than ten SRO markets, as well as
internalizing broker-dealers and various forms of alternative trading
systems (``ATSs''), including dark pools and electronic communication
networks (``ECNs''). Each SRO market competes to produce transaction
reports via trade executions, and two Financial Industry Regulatory
Authority, Inc. (``FINRA'') regulated Trade Reporting Facilities
(``TRFs'') compete to attract internalized transaction reports.
Competitive markets for order flow, executions, and transaction reports
provide pricing discipline for the inputs of proprietary data products.
The large number of SROs, TRFs, broker-dealers, and ATSs that
currently produce proprietary data or are currently capable of
producing it provides further pricing discipline for proprietary data
products. Each SRO, TRF, ATS, and broker-dealer is currently permitted
to produce proprietary data products, and many currently do or have
announced plans to do so, including NASDAQ, NYSE, NYSE Amex (now NYSE
MKT), NYSEArca, DirectEdge and BATS.
Any ATS or BD can combine with any other ATS, broker-dealer, or
multiple ATSs or broker-dealers to produce joint proprietary data
products. Additionally, order routers and market data vendors can
facilitate single or multiple broker-dealers' production of proprietary
data products. The potential sources of proprietary products are
virtually limitless.
The fact that proprietary data from ATSs, broker-dealers, and
vendors can by-pass SROs is significant in two respects. First, non-
SROs can compete directly with SROs for the production and sale of
proprietary data products as, for example, BATS and Arca did before
registering as exchanges by publishing Depth-of-Book data on the
Internet. Second, because a single order or transaction report can
appear in an SRO
[[Page 38761]]
proprietary product, a non-SRO proprietary product, or both, the data
available in proprietary products is exponentially greater than the
actual number of orders and transaction reports that exist in the
marketplace.
Market data vendors provide another form of price discipline for
proprietary data products because they control the primary means of
access to end Subscribers. Vendors impose price restraints based upon
their business models. For example, vendors such as Bloomberg and
Thomson Reuters that assess a surcharge on data they sell may refuse to
offer proprietary products that end Subscribers will not purchase in
sufficient numbers. Internet portals, such as Google, impose a
discipline by providing only data that will enable them to attract
``eyeballs'' that contribute to their advertising revenue. Retail
broker-dealers, such as Schwab and Fidelity, offer their customers
proprietary data only if it promotes trading and generates sufficient
commission revenue. Although the business models may differ, these
vendors' pricing discipline is the same: they can simply refuse to
purchase any proprietary data product that fails to provide sufficient
value. BX and other producers of proprietary data products must
understand and respond to these varying business models and pricing
disciplines in order to market proprietary data products successfully.
In addition to the competition and price discipline described
above, the market for proprietary data products is also highly
contestable because market entry is rapid, inexpensive, and profitable.
The history of electronic trading is replete with examples of entrants
that swiftly grew into some of the largest electronic trading platforms
and proprietary data producers: Archipelago, Bloomberg Tradebook,
Island, RediBook, Attain, TracECN, BATS and Direct Edge. A
proliferation of dark pools and other ATSs operate profitably with
fragmentary shares of consolidated market volume.
Regulation NMS, by deregulating the market for proprietary data,
has increased the contestability of that market. While broker-dealers
have previously published their proprietary data individually,
Regulation NMS encourages market data vendors and broker-dealers to
produce proprietary products cooperatively in a manner never before
possible. Multiple market data vendors already have the capability to
aggregate data and disseminate it on a profitable scale, including
Bloomberg, and Thomson Reuters.
Competition among platforms has driven BX continually to improve
its platform data offerings and to cater to customers' data needs. For
example, BX has developed and maintained multiple delivery mechanisms
(IP, multi-cast, and compression) that enable customers to receive data
in the form and manner they prefer and at the lowest cost to them. BX
has created new products like BX Depth, because offering data in
multiple formatting allows BX to better fit customer needs. BX offers
data via multiple extranet and telecommunication providers such as
Verizon, BT Radianz, and Savvis, among others, thereby helping to
reduce network and total cost for its data products. BX has an online
administrative system to provide customers transparency into their
datafeed requests and streamline data usage reporting. BX is also
implementing an Enterprise License option to reduce the administrative
burden and costs to firms that purchase market data.
Despite these enhancements and ever increasing message traffic,
BX's fees for market data have remained flat. The same holds true for
execution services; despite numerous enhancements to BX's trading
platform, absolute and relative trading costs have declined. Platform
competition has intensified as new entrants have emerged, constraining
prices for both executions and for data.
The vigor of competition for options data is significant and the
Exchange believes that this proposal itself clearly evidences such
competition. The Exchange has witnessed competitors creating new
products and innovative pricing in this space over the course of the
past year. BX continues to see firms challenge its pricing on the basis
of the Exchange's explicit fees being higher than the zero-priced fees
from other competitors such as BATS. In all cases, firms make decisions
on how much and what types of data to consume on the basis of the total
cost of interacting with BX or other exchanges. Of course, the explicit
data fees are but one factor in a total platform analysis. Some
competitors have lower transactions fees and higher data fees, and
others are vice versa. The market for the proposed data is highly
competitive and continually evolves as products develop and change.
C. Self-Regulatory Organization's Statement on Comments on the Proposed
Rule Change Received From Members, Participants or Others
No written comments were either solicited or received.
III. Date of Effectiveness of the Proposed Rule Change and Timing for
Commission Action
The foregoing rule change has become effective pursuant to Section
19(b)(3)(A) of the Act \23\ and paragraph (f) of Rule 19b-4
thereunder.\24\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\23\ 15 U.S.C. 78s(b)(3)(A).
\24\ 17 CFR 240.19b-4(f).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
At any time within 60 days of the filing of the proposed rule
change, the Commission summarily may temporarily suspend such rule
change if it appears to the Commission that such action is necessary or
appropriate in the public interest, for the protection of investors, or
otherwise in furtherance of the purposes of the Act.
IV. Solicitation of Comments
Interested persons are invited to submit written data, views, and
arguments concerning the foregoing, including whether the proposed rule
change is consistent with the Act. Comments may be submitted by any of
the following methods:
Electronic Comments
Use the Commission's Internet comment form (https://www.sec.gov/rules/sro.shtml); or
Send an email to rule-comments@sec.gov. Please include
File Number SR-BX-2013-040 on the subject line.
Paper Comments
Send paper comments in triplicate to Elizabeth M. Murphy,
Secretary, Securities and Exchange Commission, 100 F Street NE.,
Washington, DC 20549-1090.
All submissions should refer to File Number SR-BX-2013-040. This file
number should be included on the subject line if email is used.
To help the Commission process and review your comments more
efficiently, please use only one method. The Commission will post all
comments on the Commission's Internet Web site (https://www.sec.gov/rules/sro.shtml). Copies of the submission, all subsequent amendments,
all written statements with respect to the proposed rule change that
are filed with the Commission, and all written communications relating
to the proposed rule change between the Commission and any person,
other than those that may be withheld from the public in accordance
with the provisions of 5 U.S.C. 552, will be available for Web site
viewing and printing in the Commission's Public Reference Room, 100 F
Street NE., Washington, DC 20549, on official
[[Page 38762]]
business days between the hours of 10:00 a.m. and 3:00 p.m. Copies of
such filing also will be available for inspection and copying at the
principal offices of BX. All comments received will be posted without
change; the Commission does not edit personal identifying information
from submissions. You should submit only information that you wish to
make available publicly. All submissions should refer to File Number
SR-SR-BX-2013-040, and should be submitted on or before July 18, 2013.
For the Commission, by the Division of Trading and Markets,
pursuant to delegated authority.\25\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\25\ 17 CFR 200.30-3(a)(12).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Jill M. Peterson,
Assistant Secretary.
[FR Doc. 2013-15373 Filed 6-26-13; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 8011-01-P