Self-Regulatory Organizations; New York Stock Exchange LLC; Notice of Filing and Immediate Effectiveness of Proposed Rule Change To Establish Non-Display Usage Fees for NYSE OpenBook, NYSE Trades, and NYSE BBO and a Redistribution Fee for NYSE OpenBook, 20973-20981 [2013-08098]
Download as PDF
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 67 / Monday, April 8, 2013 / Notices
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
settling, processing information with
respect to, and facilitating transactions
in securities, to remove impediments to
and perfect the mechanism of a free and
open market and a national market
system, and, in general, to protect
investors and the public interest.
The composition and selection of the
BX Board of Directors will continue to
satisfy the requirement in Section
6(b)(3) of the Act 19 that the rules of the
Exchange provide for the fair
representation of members in the
selection of directors and administration
of the Exchange. The Exchange believes
that its By-Laws continue to assure fair
representation of the Exchange’s
members in the selection of its directors
and administration of its affairs and
provide that, among other things, one or
more directors shall be representative of
investors and not be associated with the
exchange, or with a broker or dealer.
Twenty percent of the Directors will
continue to be Member Representative
Directors as required by BX Article IV,
Section 4.3(a).
The number of Public Directors that
are required to be included in the
calculation of Non-Industry Directors
will be the same as the number required
on the Phlx and NASDAQ Boards.20 The
BX board requirements today are
otherwise similar to the requirements at
Phlx and NASDAQ. The Exchange
believes that this proposal is consistent
with the previous filing which
eliminated BOX related references from
its By-Laws.21 The number of Public
Directors in the Non-Industry Director
calculation was directly related to the
BX Board composition with BOX
representation and the elimination of
the BOX representation from the BX
Board no longer necessitates the
increased number of Public Directors.
The Exchange believes that amending
the By-Laws to reflect a similar board
composition to NASDAQ and Phlx
would continue to assure fair
representation of the Exchange’s
members in the selection of its directors
and administration of its affairs.
B. Self-Regulatory Organization’s
Statement on Burden on Competition
BX does not believe that the proposed
rule change will impose any burden on
competition not necessary or
appropriate in furtherance of the
purposes of the Act. This proposal will
continue to provide for the fair
representation of members in the
selection of directors and administration
19 15
U.S.C. 78f(b)(3).
Phlx By-Law Article III, Section 3–2(a) and
NASDAQ By-Law Article III, Section 2(a).
21 See note 7.
of the Exchange. The amendment to
amend By-Law Article IV, Section 4.3 to
modify the number of Public Directors
in the Non-Industry calculation is
similar to by-laws on other exchanges.22
C. Self-Regulatory Organization’s
Statement on Comments on the
Proposed Rule Change Received From
Members, Participants or Others
No written comments were either
solicited or received.
III. Date of Effectiveness of the
Proposed Rule Change and Timing for
Commission Action
Within 45 days of the date of
publication of this notice in the Federal
Register or within such longer period (i)
as the Commission may designate up to
90 days of such date if it finds such
longer period to be appropriate and
publishes its reasons for so finding or
(ii) as to which the Exchange consents,
the Commission shall: (a) by order
approve or disapprove such proposed
rule change, or (b) institute proceedings
to determine whether the proposed rule
change should be disapproved.
IV. Solicitation of Comments
Interested persons are invited to
submit written data, views, and
arguments concerning the foregoing,
including whether the proposed rule
change is consistent with the Act.
Comments may be submitted by any of
the following methods:
Electronic Comments
• Use the Commission’s Internet
comment form (https://www.sec.gov/
rules/sro.shtml); or
• Send an email to rulecomments@sec.gov. Please include File
Number SR–BX–2013–029 on the
subject line.
Paper Comments
• Send paper comments in triplicate
to Elizabeth M. Murphy, Secretary,
Securities and Exchange Commission,
100 F Street NE., Washington, DC
20549–1090.
All submissions should refer to File
Number SR–BX–2013–029. This file
number should be included on the
subject line if email is used. To help the
Commission process and review your
comments more efficiently, please use
only one method. The Commission will
post all comments on the Commission’s
Internet Web site (https://www.sec.gov/
rules/sro.shtml). Copies of the
submission, all subsequent
amendments, all written statements
VerDate Mar<15>2010
20:02 Apr 05, 2013
Jkt 229001
with respect to the proposed rule
change that are filed with the
Commission, and all written
communications relating to the
proposed rule change between the
Commission and any person, other than
those that may be withheld from the
public in accordance with the
provisions of 5 U.S.C. 552, will be
available for Web site viewing and
printing in the Commission’s Public
Reference Room, 100 F Street NE.,
Washington, DC 20549, on official
business days between the hours of
10:00 a.m. and 3:00 p.m. Copies of such
filing also will be available for
inspection and copying at the principal
offices of the Exchange. All comments
received will be posted without change;
the Commission does not edit personal
identifying information from
submissions. You should submit only
information that you wish to make
available publicly. All submissions
should refer to File Number SR–BX–
2013–029, and should be submitted on
or before April 29, 2013.
For the Commission, by the Division of
Trading and Markets, pursuant to delegated
authority.23
Kevin M. O’Neill,
Deputy Secretary.
[FR Doc. 2013–08099 Filed 4–5–13; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 8011–01–P
SECURITIES AND EXCHANGE
COMMISSION
[Release No. 34–69278; File No. SR–NYSE–
2013–25]
Self-Regulatory Organizations; New
York Stock Exchange LLC; Notice of
Filing and Immediate Effectiveness of
Proposed Rule Change To Establish
Non-Display Usage Fees for NYSE
OpenBook, NYSE Trades, and NYSE
BBO and a Redistribution Fee for
NYSE OpenBook
April 2, 2013.
Pursuant to Section 19(b)(1) 1 of the
Securities Exchange Act of 1934 (the
‘‘Act’’) 2 and Rule 19b–4 thereunder,3
notice is hereby given that, on March
21, 2013, New York Stock Exchange
LLC (‘‘NYSE’’ or the ‘‘Exchange’’) filed
with the Securities and Exchange
Commission (the ‘‘Commission’’) the
proposed rule change as described in
Items I, II, and III below, which Items
have been prepared by the selfregulatory organization. The
Commission is publishing this notice to
23 17
CFR 200.30–3(a)(12).
U.S.C. 78s(b)(1).
2 15 U.S.C. 78a.
3 17 CFR 240.19b–4.
1 15
20 See
22 See Phlx By-Law Article III, Section 3–2(a) and
NASDAQ By-Law Article III, Section 2(a).
PO 00000
Frm 00091
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
20973
E:\FR\FM\08APN1.SGM
08APN1
20974
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 67 / Monday, April 8, 2013 / Notices
solicit comments on the proposed rule
change from interested persons.
I. Self-Regulatory Organization’s
Statement of the Terms of Substance of
the Proposed Rule Change
The Exchange proposes to establish
non-display usage fees for NYSE
OpenBook, NYSE Trades, and NYSE
BBO and a redistribution fee for NYSE
OpenBook, all of which will be
operative on April 1, 2013. The text of
the proposed rule change is available on
the Exchange’s Web site at
www.nyse.com, at the principal office of
the Exchange, and at the Commission’s
Public Reference Room.
II. Self-Regulatory Organization’s
Statement of the Purpose of, and
Statutory Basis for, the Proposed Rule
Change
In its filing with the Commission, the
self-regulatory organization included
Product
statements concerning the purpose of,
and basis for, the proposed rule change
and discussed any comments it received
on the proposed rule change. The text
of those statements may be examined at
the places specified in Item IV below.
The Exchange has prepared summaries,
set forth in sections A, B, and C below,
of the most significant parts of such
statements.
A. Self-Regulatory Organization’s
Statement of the Purpose of, and the
Statutory Basis for, the Proposed Rule
Change
1. Purpose
The Exchange proposes to establish
non-display usage fees for NYSE
OpenBook, NYSE Trades, and NYSE
BBO and a redistribution fee for NYSE
OpenBook, all of which will be
operative on April 1, 2013. The
subsections below describe (1) the
background on the current fees for these
real-time products; (2) the rationale for
creating a new non-display usage fee
structure; (3) the proposed fees for nondisplay use, which will include internal
non-display use and managed nondisplay use; (4) the proposed
redistribution fee for NYSE OpenBook;
(5) examples comparing the current and
proposed fees; and (6) a correction to
the Market Data Fee schedule.
Background on Current Fees
The current monthly fees for NYSE
OpenBook,4 NYSE BBO,5 and NYSE
Trades 6 are as follows:
Subscriber Fees
Digital Media Enterprise Fee
Professional: $60 Non-professional: $15 Non-professional Fee Cap: $25,000.
Professional: $15 Non-professional: $5 ....................
Professional: $15 .......................................................
N/A ...........................
N/A.
N/A ...........................
$40,000 ....................
N/A.
$1,000 (operative
May 1, 2013).
Access Fee
NYSE OpenBook 7 ...........
$5,000
NYSE BBO ......................
NYSE Trades ...................
8 1,500
1,500
Redistribution Fee
i. Vendors.
• ‘‘Vendors’’ are market data vendors,
broker-dealers, private network providers,
and other entities that control Subscribers’
access to a market data product through
Subscriber Entitlement Controls (as described
below).
ii. Subscribers.
• ‘‘Subscribers’’ are unique individual
persons or devices (which include both
display and non-display devices) to which a
Vendor provides a market data product. Any
individual or device that receives the market
data product from a Vendor is a Subscriber,
whether the individual or device works for
or belongs to the Vendor, or works for or
belongs to an entity other than the Vendor.
• Only a Vendor may control Subscriber
access to the market data product.
• Subscribers may not redistribute the
market data product in any manner.
iii. Subscriber Entitlements.
• A Subscriber Entitlement is a Vendor’s
permitting a Subscriber to receive access to
the market data product through an
Exchange-approved Subscriber Entitlement
Control.
• A Vendor may not provide access to a
market data product to a Subscriber except
through a unique Subscriber Entitlement.
• The Exchange will require each Vendor
to provide a unique Subscriber Entitlement to
each unique Subscriber.
• At prescribed intervals (normally
monthly), the Exchange will require each
Vendor to report each unique Subscriber
Entitlement.
iv. Subscriber Entitlement Controls.
• A Subscriber Entitlement Control is the
Vendor’s process of permitting Subscribers’
access to a market data product.
• Prior to using any Subscriber Entitlement
Control or changing a previously approved
Subscriber Entitlement Control, a Vendor
must provide the Exchange with a
demonstration and a detailed written
description of the control or change and the
Exchange must have approved it in writing.
• The Exchange will approve a Subscriber
Entitlement Control if it allows only
authorized, unique end-users or devices to
access the market data product or monitors
access to the market data product by each
unique end-user or device.
• Vendors must design Subscriber
Entitlement Controls to produce an audit
report and make each audit report available
to the Exchange upon request. The audit
report must identify:
• Each entitlement update to the
Subscriber Entitlement Control;
4 See Securities Exchange Act Release Nos. 59544
(Mar. 9, 2009), 74 FR 11162 (Mar. 16, 2009) (SR–
NYSE–2008–131) and 62038 (May 5, 2010), 75 FR
26825 (May 12, 2010) (SR–NYSE–2010–22).
5 See Securities Exchange Act Release No. 62181
(May 26, 2010), 75 FR 31488 (June 3, 2010) (SR–
NYSE–2010–30).
6 See SR–NYSE–2013–24.
7 The NYSE OpenBook Bundle pricing package
includes: (i) NYSE OpenBook Realtime, by which
the Exchange makes NYSE OpenBook Realtime
available on a snapshot basis, with updates
distributed in real-time at intervals of one second;
and (ii) NYSE OpenBook Ultra, by which the
Exchange updates NYSE OpenBook information
upon receipt of each displayed limit order, or upon
an event that removes limit orders from NYSE
OpenBook (i.e., cancellation or execution). For no
additional charge, the Exchange makes available to
recipients of NYSE OpenBook additional data feeds
containing NYSE BBO and Order Imbalance
Information. See Securities Exchange Act Release
No. 59544 (Mar. 9, 2009), 74 FR 11162 (Mar. 16,
2009) (SR–NYSE–2008–131).
8 One $1,500 monthly access fee entitles a vendor
to receive both the NYSE BBO data feed as well as
the Exchange’s NYSE Trades data feed. See supra
n.5.
9 See Securities Exchange Act Release Nos. 62038
(May 5, 2010), 75 FR 26825 (May 12, 2010) (SR–
NYSE–2010–22); 62181 (May 26, 2010), 75 FR
31488 (June 3, 2010) (SR–NYSE–2010–30); and
59290 (Jan. 23, 2009), 74 FR 5707 (Jan. 30, 2009)
(SR–NYSE–2009–05).
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
While the majority of subscribers pay
the subscriber fee for each display or
non-display device that has access to
the market data products as set forth
above, a small number of vendors and
subscribers are eligible for, and have
elected, the NYSE Unit-of-Count Policy
that was first introduced as an NYSE
OpenBook pilot in 2009 and is now also
available for NYSE BBO and NYSE
Trades.9 Under this fee structure, these
vendors and subscribers are subject to a
fee structure that utilizes the following
basic principles:
VerDate Mar<15>2010
20:02 Apr 05, 2013
Jkt 229001
PO 00000
Frm 00092
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
E:\FR\FM\08APN1.SGM
08APN1
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 67 / Monday, April 8, 2013 / Notices
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
• The status of the Subscriber Entitlement
Control; and
• Any other changes to the Subscriber
Entitlement Control over a given period.
• Only the Vendor may have access to
Subscriber Entitlement Controls.
Vendors must count every Subscriber
Entitlement, whether it be an individual
person or a device. Thus, the Vendor’s
count would include every person and
device that accesses the data regardless
of the purpose for which the individual
or device uses the data.
Vendors must report all Subscriber
Entitlements in accordance with the
following:
i. In connection with a Vendor’s
external distribution of the market data
product, the Vendor should count as
one Subscriber Entitlement each unique
Subscriber that the Vendor has entitled
to have access to the market data
product. However, where a device is
dedicated specifically to a single
individual, the Vendor should count
only the individual and need not count
the device.
ii. In connection with a Vendor’s
internal distribution of a market data
product, the Vendor should count as
one Subscriber Entitlement each unique
individual (but not devices) that the
Vendor has entitled to have access to
such market data.
iii. The Vendor should identify and
report each unique Subscriber. If a
Subscriber uses the same unique
Subscriber Entitlement to gain access to
multiple market data services, the
Vendor should count that as one
Subscriber Entitlement. However, if a
unique Subscriber uses multiple
Subscriber Entitlements to gain access
to one or more market data services
(e.g., a single Subscriber has multiple
passwords and user identifications), the
Vendor should report all of those
Subscriber Entitlements.
iv. Vendors should report each unique
individual person who receives access
through multiple devices as one
Subscriber Entitlement so long as each
device is dedicated specifically to that
individual.
v. The Vendor should include in the
count as one Subscriber Entitlement
devices serving no entitled individuals.
However, if the Vendor entitles one or
more individuals to use the same
device, the Vendor should include only
the entitled individuals, and not the
device, in the count.
Rationale for New Non-Display Usage
Fee Structure
As noted in the original NYSE Unitof-Count Policy proposal, ‘‘technology
has made it increasingly difficult to
define ‘device’ and to control who has
VerDate Mar<15>2010
20:02 Apr 05, 2013
Jkt 229001
access to devices, [and] the markets
have struggled to make device counts
uniform among their customers.’’ 10
Significant change has characterized the
industry in recent years, stemming in
large measure from changes in
regulation and technological advances,
which has led to the rise in automated
and algorithmic trading. Additionally,
market data feeds have become faster
and contain a vastly larger number of
quotes and trades. Today, a majority of
trading is done by leveraging nondisplay devices consuming massive
amounts of data. Some firms base their
business models largely on
incorporating non-display data into
applications and do not require
widespread data access by the firm’s
employees. Changes in market data
consumption patterns have increased
the use and importance of non-display
data.
Applications that can be used in nondisplay devices provide added value in
their capability to manipulate and
spread the data they consume. Such
applications have the ability to perform
calculations on the live data stream and
manufacture new data out of it. Data can
be processed much faster by a nondisplay device than it can be by a
human being processing information
that he or she views on a data terminal.
Non-display devices also can dispense
data to multiple computer applications
as compared with the restriction of data
to one display terminal.
While the non-display data has
become increasingly valuable to data
recipients who can use it to generate
substantial profits, it has become
increasing difficult for them and the
Exchange to accurately count nondisplay devices. The number and type
of non-display devices, as well as their
complexity and interconnectedness,
have grown in recent years, creating
administrative challenges for vendors,
data recipients, and the Exchange to
accurately count such devices and audit
such counts. Unlike a display device,
such as a Bloomberg terminal, it is not
possible to simply walk through a
trading floor or areas of a data
recipient’s premises to identify nondisplay devices. During an audit, an
auditor must review a firm’s entitlement
10 See Securities Exchange Act Release No. 59544
(Mar. 9, 2009), 74 FR 11162 (Mar. 16, 2009) (SR–
NYSE–2008–131). At least one other Exchange also
has noted such administrative challenges. In
establishing a non-display usage fee for internal
distributors of TotalView and OpenView, NASDAQ
Stock Market LLC (‘‘NASDAQ’’) noted that as ‘‘the
number of devices increase, so does the
administrative burden on the end customer of
counting these devices.’’ See Securities Exchange
Act Release No. 61700 (Mar. 12, 2010), 75 FR 13172
(Mar. 18, 2010) (SR–NASDAQ–2010–034).
PO 00000
Frm 00093
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
20975
report to determine usage. While
display use is generally associated with
an individual end user and/or unique
user ID, a non-display use is more
difficult to account for because the
entitlement report may show a server
name or Internet protocol (‘‘IP’’) address
or it may not. The auditor must review
each IP or server and further inquire
about downstream use and quantity of
servers with access to data; this type of
counting is very labor-intensive and
prone to inaccuracies.
For these reasons, the Exchange
determined that its current fee structure,
which is based on counting non-display
devices, is no longer appropriate in light
of market and technology developments
and does not reflect the value of the
non-display data and its many profitgenerating uses for subscribers. As such,
the Exchange, in conjunction with its
domestic and foreign affiliate
exchanges, undertook a review of its
market data policies with a goal of
bringing greater consistency and clarity
to its fee structure; easing
administration for itself, vendors, and
subscribers; and setting fees at a level
that better reflects the current value of
the data provided. As a result of this
review, the Exchange has determined to
offer a new fee structure for display and
non-display use of certain market data
products. Initially, the Exchange will
implement the new non-display use fee
structure for NYSE OpenBook, NYSE
BBO, and NYSE Trades, operative on
April 1, 2013. The Exchange anticipates
implementing a new display use fee
structure later this year; until such time,
existing fees for display use will apply.
Proposed Non-Display Usage Fees
The Exchange proposes to establish
new monthly fees for non-display usage,
which for purposes of the proposed fee
structure will mean accessing,
processing or consuming an NYSE data
product delivered via direct and/or
Redistributor 11 data feeds, for a purpose
other than in support of its display or
further internal or external
redistribution. The proposed nondisplay fees will apply to the nondisplay use of the data product as part
of automated calculations or algorithms
to support trading decision-making
processes or the operation of trading
platforms (‘‘Non-Display Trading
Activities’’). They include, but are not
limited to, high frequency trading,
automated order or quote generation
and/or order pegging, or price
11 ‘‘Redistributor’’ means a vendor or any other
person that provides an NYSE data product to a
data recipient or to any system that a data recipient
uses, irrespective of the means of transmission or
access.
E:\FR\FM\08APN1.SGM
08APN1
20976
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 67 / Monday, April 8, 2013 / Notices
referencing for the purposes of
algorithmic trading and/or smart order
routing. Applications and devices that
solely facilitate display, internal
distribution, or redistribution of the data
product with no other uses and
applications that use the data product
for other non-trading activities, such as
the creation of derived data, quantitative
analysis, fund administration, portfolio
management, and compliance, are not
covered by the proposed non-display fee
structure and are subject to the current
standard per-device fee structure. The
Exchange reserves the right to audit data
recipients’ use of NYSE market data
products in Non-Display Trading
Activities in accordance with NYSE’s
vendor and subscriber agreements.
There will be two types of fees, which
are described below. The first type of fee
is for internal non-display use. The
second type of fee is for managed nondisplay services. The current NYSE
Unit-of-Count Policy will no longer
apply to any non-display usage.12
Proposed Fees for Internal Non-Display
Use
The proposed internal non-display
use fees will apply to NYSE OpenBook,
NYSE BBO, and NYSE Trades. Internal
non-display use occurs when a data
recipient either manages its own nondisplay infrastructure and controls the
access to and permissioning of the
market data product on its non-display
applications or when the data
recipient’s non-display applications are
hosted by a third party that has not been
approved to provide the managed nondisplay services as described below.
The fee structure will have three
categories, which recognize the different
uses for the market data. Category 1 Fees
apply where a data recipient’s nondisplay use of real time market data is
for the purpose of principal trading.
Category 2 Fees apply where a data
recipient’s non-display use of market
data is for the purpose of broker/agency
trading, i.e., trading-based activities to
facilitate the recipient’s customers’
business. If a data recipient trades both
on a principal and agency basis, then
the data recipient must pay both
categories of fees. Category 3 Fees apply
where a data recipient’s non-display use
of market data is, in whole or in part,
for the purpose of providing reference
prices in the operation of one or more
trading platforms, including but not
limited to multilateral trading facilities,
alternative trading systems, broker
crossing networks, dark pools, and
systematic internalization systems. A
data recipient will not be liable for
Category 3 Fees for those market data
products for which it is also paying
Category 1 and/or Category 2 Fees.
The fees for internal non-display use
per data recipient organization for each
category will be as follows:
Category 1
trading as
principal
(per month)
Product
NYSE OpenBook .........................................................................................................................
NYSE BBO ..................................................................................................................................
NYSE Trades ...............................................................................................................................
Subscribers to NYSE OpenBook,
which includes access to NYSE BBO
and NYSE Order Imbalances, are not
required to subscribe to these two
individual services as part of the nondisplay activity for these products.13
Subscribers who are not currently
subscribing to NYSE OpenBook Bundle
pricing package 14 will be responsible
for the individual product licenses for
the non-display activity.
For internal non-display use, there
will be no reporting requirements
regarding non-display device counts,
thus doing away with the administrative
burdens described above. Data
recipients will be required to declare the
market data products used within their
non-display trading applications by
executing an NYSE Euronext NonDisplay Usage Declaration.
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
Proposed Fees for Managed Non-Display
Services
The Exchange also proposes to
establish fees for managed non-display
services for NYSE OpenBook and NYSE
Trades. Under the managed non-display
service, a data recipient’s non-display
12 Existing customers that are approved for the
NYSE Unit-of-Count Policy for display usage may
continue to follow that Policy until the new display
fees are implemented.
VerDate Mar<15>2010
20:02 Apr 05, 2013
Jkt 229001
applications must be hosted by a
Redistributor approved by the
Exchange, and this Redistributor must
manage and control the access to NYSE
OpenBook and/or NYSE Trades for
these applications and may not allow
for further internal distribution or
external redistribution of these market
data products. The Redistributor of the
managed non-display services and the
data recipient must be approved under
the current NYSE Unit-of-Count policy
described above,15 which will no longer
be available for non-display use after the
proposed fees are implemented. If a data
recipient is receiving NYSE OpenBook
and/or NYSE Trades for Non-Display
Trading Activities from a Redistributor
that is not approved under the NYSE
Unit-of-Count policy, then the internal
non-display fees described above will
apply.
The fees for managed non-display
services per data recipient organization
will be as follows:
13 There is currently a $500/month access fee for
the NYSE Order Imbalances data feed.
14 See supra n.7
PO 00000
Frm 00094
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
Category 2
trading as
broker/agency
(per month)
$5,000
1,500
2,000
$5,000
1,500
2,000
Product
NYSE OpenBook ..................
NYSE Trades ........................
Category 3
trading
platform
(per month)
$5,000
1,500
2,000
Managed
non-display
use fee
(per month)
$2,000
700
Data recipients will not be liable for
managed non-display fees for those
market data products for which they pay
the internal non-display fee.
Upon request, a Redistributor offering
managed non-display services must
provide the Exchange with a list of data
recipients that are receiving NYSE
OpenBook or NYSE Trades through the
Redistributor’s managed non-display
service. Data recipients of the managed
non-display service have no additional
reporting requirements, thus easing the
administrative burdens described above.
NYSE OpenBook Redistribution Fee
The Exchange proposes to establish a
monthly redistribution fee of $3,000 for
NYSE OpenBook. The Exchange
believes that it is reasonable to charge
this redistribution fee because vendors
receive value from redistributing the
15 See
E:\FR\FM\08APN1.SGM
supra n.9.
08APN1
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 67 / Monday, April 8, 2013 / Notices
data in their business products for their
customers.
Examples
Broker-Dealer A obtains NYSE
OpenBook directly from the Exchange
for internal use and does not fall under
the NYSE Unit-of-Count Policy. BrokerDealer A trades both on a principal and
agency basis and has (i) 80 individual
persons who use 100 display devices
and (ii) 50 non-display devices.
• Under the current fee schedule,
Broker-Dealer A pays the Exchange the
$5,000 access fee plus $60 for each of
the 100 display devices (although 80
individual persons use them, the
number of devices is counted), or
$6,000, and $60 for each of the 50 nondisplay devices, or $3,000, for a total of
$14,000 per month.
• Under the proposed fee schedule,
Broker-Dealer A would pay the
Exchange the $5,000 access fee plus $60
for each of the 100 display devices, or
$6,000, and Category 1 and Category 2
fees for internal non-display use, or
$10,000, for a total of $21,000 per
month. No redistribution fee would be
charged.
Broker-Dealer B, which only trades as
principal, obtains NYSE OpenBook from
Vendor X. Broker-Dealer B and Vendor
X are both approved for the NYSE Unitof-Count Policy. Broker-Dealer B has (i)
10 individual persons who use 12
display devices and (ii) 5 non-display
devices.
• Under the current fee schedule,
Vendor X pays the $5,000 access fee and
Broker-Dealer B pays $900 ($60 for the
10 individual persons (under the NYSE
Unit-of-Count Policy, the larger number
of display devices is not counted), or
$600, plus $60 for each of the 5 nondisplay devices, or $300).
• Under the proposed fee schedule,
Broker-Dealer B would pay $600 as it
does today for its individual persons
using display devices, and $2,000 for
managed non-display use, for a total of
$2,600 per month in fees. Vendor X
would pay the $5,000 access fee and the
$3,000 redistribution fee, for a total of
$8,000 per month.
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
Correction to Market Data Fee Schedule
The Exchange recently created a
Market Data Fee Schedule. The
Exchange proposes to correct the
subscriber fee line for NYSE Trades to
reflect that there is only a professional
subscriber fee and no non-professional
subscriber fee.16
16 See Securities Exchange Act Release No. 59309
(Jan. 28, 2009) 74 FR 6073 (Feb. 4, 2009) (SR–
NYSE–2009–04).
VerDate Mar<15>2010
20:02 Apr 05, 2013
Jkt 229001
2. Statutory Basis
The Exchange believes that the
proposed rule change is consistent with
the provisions of Section 6 of the Act,17
in general, and Sections 6(b)(4) and
6(b)(5) of the Act,18 in particular, in that
it provides an equitable allocation of
reasonable fees among users and
recipients of the data and is not
designed to permit unfair
discrimination among customers,
issuers, and brokers.
As described in detail in the section
‘‘Rationale for New Non-Display Usage
Fee Structure’’ above, which is
incorporated by reference herein,
technology has made it increasingly
difficult to define ‘‘device’’ and to
control who has access to devices.
Significant change has characterized the
industry in recent years, stemming in
large measure from changes in
regulation and technological advances,
which has led to the rise in automated
and algorithmic trading, which have the
potential to generate substantial profits.
Indeed, data used in a single nondisplay device running a single trading
algorithm can generate large profits.
Market data technology and usage has
evolved to the point where it is no
longer practical, nor fair and equitable,
to simply count non-display devices.
The administrative costs and difficulties
of establishing reliable counts and
conducting an effective audit of nondisplay devices have become too
burdensome, impractical, and noneconomic for the Exchange, vendors,
and data recipients. Rather, the
Exchange believes that its proposed flat
fee structure for non-display use is
reasonable, equitable, and not unfairly
discriminatory in light of these
developments.
Other exchanges also have established
differentiated fees based on non-display
usage, including a flat or enterprise fee.
For example, NASDAQ professional
subscribers pay monthly fees for nondisplay usage based upon direct access
to NASDAQ Level 2, NASDAQ
TotalView, or NASDAQ OpenView,
which range from $300 per month for
customers with one to 10 subscribers to
$75,000 for customers with 250 or more
subscribers.19 In addition, NASDAQ
OMX PHLX, Inc. (‘‘Phlx’’) offers an
alternative $10,000 per month ‘‘NonDisplay Enterprise License’’ fee that
permits distribution to an unlimited
number of internal non-display
subscribers without incurring additional
17 15
U.S.C. 78f(b).
U.S.C. 78f(b)(4), (5).
19 See NASDAQ Rule 7023(b)(4).
18 15
PO 00000
Frm 00095
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
20977
fees for each internal subscriber.20 The
Non-Display Enterprise License covers
non-display subscriber fees for all Phlx
proprietary direct data feed products
and is in addition to any other
associated distributor fees for Phlx
proprietary direct data feed products.
NASDAQ OMX BX, Inc. (‘‘BX’’) also
offers an alternative non-display usage
fee of $16,000 for its BX TotalView data
feed.21 NASDAQ and Phlx also both
offer managed non-display data
solutions at higher overall fees than the
Exchange proposes to charge.22
The Exchange also believes that it is
reasonable, equitable, and not unfairly
discriminatory to charge relatively
lower fees for managed non-display
services because the Exchange expects
that they will generally be used by a
small number of Redistributors and data
recipients that are currently eligible for
the NYSE Unit-of-Count Policy. These
data recipients are constrained by
whatever applications are available via
Redistributors operating in the
Exchange’s co-location center and other
hosted facilities. In comparison, a data
recipient that elects internal nondisplay use is free to use the data in any
manner it chooses and create new uses
in an unlimited number of non-display
devices. The lack of constraint in this
regard will make the non-display usage
of the data more valuable to such an
internal use data recipient.
The proposed redistribution fee for
NYSE OpenBook also is reasonable
because it is comparable to other
redistribution fees that are currently
charged by other exchanges.23 As noted
20 See Securities Exchange Act Release No. 68576
(Jan. 3, 2013), 78 FR 1886 (Jan. 9, 2013) (SR–Phlx–
2012–145). Alternatively, Phlx charges each
professional subscriber $40 per month.
21 See NASDAQ OMX BX Rule 7023(a)(2).
Alternatively, BX charges each professional
subscriber $40 per month.
22 NASDAQ established fees for a Managed Data
Solution to Distributors, which includes a monthly
Managed Data Solution Administration fee of
$1,500 and monthly Subscriber fees ranging from
$60 to $300. See NASDAQ Rule 7026(b). Phlx also
established a Managed Data Solution, which
includes a monthly Managed Data Solution
Administration fee of $1,500 and a monthly
Subscriber fee of $250. The monthly License fee is
in addition to Phlx’s monthly Distributor fee of
$2,500 (for external usage), and the $250 monthly
Subscriber fee is assessed for each Subscriber of a
Managed Data Solution. See Securities Exchange
Act Release No. 67466 (July 19, 2012), 77 FR 43629
(July 25, 2012) (SR–Phlx–2012–93).
23 NYSE Arca, Inc. (‘‘NYSE Arca’’) charges a
$3,000 per month redistribution fee for the NYSE
Arca Integrated Feed, which includes depth-of-book
data. See Securities Exchange Act Release No.
66128 (Jan. 10, 2012), 77 FR 2331 (Jan. 17, 2012)
(SR–NYSEArca–2011–96). In addition, NYSE Arca
and NYSE MKT LLC (‘‘NYSE MKT’’) charge
redistribution fees of $2,000 per month for certain
proprietary options market data products. See
Securities Exchange Act Release Nos. 68005 (Oct.
Continued
E:\FR\FM\08APN1.SGM
08APN1
20978
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 67 / Monday, April 8, 2013 / Notices
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
above, the Exchange believes that it is
reasonable to charge redistribution fees
because vendors receive value from
redistributing the data in their business
products for their customers. The
redistribution fees also are equitable and
not unfairly discriminatory because they
will be charged on an equal basis to
those vendors that choose to redistribute
the data.
The Exchange has not recently raised
the market data fees for these three
proprietary products. The Exchange set
the NYSE OpenBook professional
subscriber fee at $60 per device in 2006,
the NYSE Trades subscriber fee at $15
per device in 2009, and the NYSE BBO
professional subscriber fee at $15 per
device in 2010.24 The Exchange believes
that the new fee schedule, which may
result in certain vendors and data
recipients paying more than they have
in the last several years, is fair and
reasonable in light of market and
technology developments. The current
per-device fee structure no longer
reflects the significant overall value that
non-display data can provide in trading
algorithms and other uses that provide
professional users with the potential to
generate substantial profits. The
Exchange believes that it is equitable
and not unfairly discriminatory to
establish an overall monthly fee that
better reflects the value of the data to
the data recipients in their profitgenerating activities and does away with
the burden of counting non-display
devices.
The Exchange also notes that products
described herein are entirely optional.
Firms are not required to purchase
NYSE OpenBook, NYSE BBO, or NYSE
Trades. Firms have a wide variety of
alternative market data products from
which to choose.25 Moreover, the
Exchange is not required to make these
proprietary data products available or to
offer any specific pricing alternatives to
any customers.
The decision of the United States
Court of Appeals for the District of
Columbia Circuit in NetCoalition v.
SEC, 615 F.3d 525 (D.C. Cir. 2010),
upheld reliance by the Securities and
Exchange Commission (‘‘Commission’’)
9, 2012), 77 FR 63362 (Oct. 16, 2012) (SR–
NYSEArca–2012–106), and 68004 (Oct. 9, 2012), 77
FR 62582 (Oct. 15, 2012) (SR–NYSEMKT–2012–49).
All distributors of a NASDAQ Last Sale Data Feed
also pay a monthly fee of $1,500. See NASDAQ
Rule 7039(d).
24 See Securities Exchange Act Release Nos.
53585 (March 31, 2006), 71 FR 17934 (April 7,
2006) (SR–NYSE–2004–43 and SR–NYSE–2005–
32); 59606 (Mar. 19, 2009), 74 FR 13293 (Mar. 26,
2009) (SR–NYSE–2009–04); and 62181 (May 26,
2010), 75 FR 31488 (June 3, 2010) (SR–NYSE–2010–
30).
25 See supra nn.19–22.
VerDate Mar<15>2010
20:02 Apr 05, 2013
Jkt 229001
upon the existence of competitive
market mechanisms to set reasonable
and equitably allocated fees for
proprietary market data:
In fact, the legislative history
indicates that the Congress intended
that the market system ‘evolve through
the interplay of competitive forces as
unnecessary regulatory restrictions are
removed’ and that the SEC wield its
regulatory power ‘in those situations
where competition may not be
sufficient,’ such as in the creation of a
‘consolidated transactional reporting
system.’
Id. at 535 (quoting H.R. Rep. No. 94–
229 at 92 (1975), as reprinted in 1975
U.S.C.C.A.N. 323). The court agreed
with the Commission’s conclusion that
‘‘Congress intended that ‘competitive
forces should dictate the services and
practices that constitute the U.S.
national market system for trading
equity securities.’ ’’ 26
As explained below in the Exchange’s
Statement on Burden on Competition,
the Exchange believes that there is
substantial evidence of competition in
the marketplace for data and that the
Commission can rely upon such
evidence in concluding that the fees
established in this filing are the product
of competition and therefore satisfy the
relevant statutory standards.27 In
addition, the existence of alternatives to
these data products, such as proprietary
last sale data from other sources, as
described below, further ensures that
the Exchange cannot set unreasonable
fees, or fees that are unreasonably
discriminatory, when vendors and
subscribers can elect such alternatives.
As the NetCoalition decision noted,
the Commission is not required to
undertake a cost-of-service or
ratemaking approach, and the Exchange
incorporates by reference into this
proposed rule change its affiliate’s
analysis of this topic in another rule
filing.28
For these reasons, the Exchange
believes that the proposed fees are
reasonable, equitable, and not unfairly
discriminatory.
B. Self-Regulatory Organization’s
Statement on Burden on Competition
The Exchange does not believe that
the proposed rule change will impose
26 NetCoalition,
615 F.3d at 535.
916 of the Dodd-Frank Wall Street
Reform and Consumer Protection Act of 2010 (the
‘‘Dodd-Frank Act’’) amended paragraph (A) of
Section 19(b)(3) of the Act, 15 U.S.C. 78s(b)(3), to
make clear that all exchange fees for market data
may be filed by exchanges on an immediately
effective basis.
28 See Securities Exchange Act Release No. 63291
(Nov. 9, 2010), 75 FR 70311 (Nov. 17, 2010) (SR–
NYSEArca–2010–97).
27 Section
PO 00000
Frm 00096
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
any burden on competition that is not
necessary or appropriate in furtherance
of the purposes of the Act. An
exchange’s ability to price its
proprietary data feed products is
constrained by actual competition for
the sale of proprietary market data
products, the joint product nature of
exchange platforms, and the existence of
alternatives to the Exchange’s
proprietary last sale data.
The Existence of Actual Competition.
The market for proprietary data
products is currently competitive and
inherently contestable because there is
fierce competition for the inputs
necessary for the creation of proprietary
data and strict pricing discipline for the
proprietary products themselves.
Numerous exchanges compete with
each other for listings and order flow
and sales of market data itself, providing
virtually limitless opportunities for
entrepreneurs who wish to compete in
any or all of those areas, including
producing and distributing their own
market data. Proprietary data products
are produced and distributed by each
individual exchange, as well as other
entities, in a vigorously competitive
market.
Competitive markets for listings, order
flow, executions, and transaction
reports provide pricing discipline for
the inputs of proprietary data products
and therefore constrain markets from
overpricing proprietary market data.
The U.S. Department of Justice also has
acknowledged the aggressive
competition among exchanges,
including for the sale of proprietary
market data itself. In announcing that
the bid for NYSE Euronext by NASDAQ
OMX Group Inc. and
IntercontinentalExchange Inc. had been
abandoned, Assistant Attorney General
Christine Varney stated that exchanges
‘‘compete head to head to offer real-time
equity data products. These data
products include the best bid and offer
of every exchange and information on
each equity trade, including the last
sale.’’ 29
It is common for broker-dealers to
further exploit this recognized
competitive constraint by sending their
order flow and transaction reports to
multiple markets, rather than providing
them all to a single market. As a 2010
Commission Concept Release noted, the
‘‘current market structure can be
described as dispersed and complex’’
29 Press Release, U.S. Department of Justice,
Assistant Attorney General Christine Varney Holds
Conference Call Regarding NASDAQ OMX Group
Inc. and IntercontinentalExchange Inc. Abandoning
Their Bid for NYSE Euronext (May 16, 2011),
available at https://www.justice.gov/iso/opa/atr/
speeches/2011/at-speech-110516.html.
E:\FR\FM\08APN1.SGM
08APN1
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 67 / Monday, April 8, 2013 / Notices
with ‘‘trading volume * * * dispersed
among many highly automated trading
centers that compete for order flow in
the same stocks’’ and ‘‘trading centers
offer[ing] a wide range of services that
are designed to attract different types of
market participants with varying trading
needs.’’ 30
In addition, in the case of products
that are distributed through market data
vendors, the market data vendors
themselves provide additional price
discipline for proprietary data products
because they control the primary means
of access to certain end users. These
vendors impose price discipline based
upon their business models. For
example, vendors that assess a
surcharge on data they sell are able to
refuse to offer proprietary products that
their end users do not or will not
purchase in sufficient numbers. Internet
portals, such as Google, impose price
discipline by providing only data that
they believe will enable them to attract
‘‘eyeballs’’ that contribute to their
advertising revenue. Similarly, vendors
will not elect to make available the
NYSE products described herein unless
their customers request them, and
customers will not elect to purchase
them unless they can be used for profitgenerating purposes. All of these
operate as constraints on pricing
proprietary data products.
Joint Product Nature of Exchange
Platform. Transaction execution and
proprietary data products are
complementary in that market data is
both an input and a byproduct of the
execution service. In fact, market data
and trade executions are a paradigmatic
example of joint products with joint
costs. The decision whether and on
which platform to post an order will
depend on the attributes of the
platforms where the order can be
posted, including the execution fees,
data quality, and price and distribution
of their data products. The more trade
executions a platform does, the more
valuable its market data products
become.
The costs of producing market data
include not only the costs of the data
distribution infrastructure, but also the
costs of designing, maintaining, and
operating the exchange’s transaction
execution platform and the cost of
regulating the exchange to ensure its fair
operation and maintain investor
30 Concept Release on Equity Market Structure,
Securities Exchange Act Release No. 61358 (Jan. 14,
2010), 75 FR 3594 (Jan. 21, 2010) (File No. S7–02–
10). This Concept Release included data from the
third quarter of 2009 showing that no market center
traded more than 20% of the volume of listed
stocks, further evidencing the dispersal of and
competition for trading activity. Id. at 3598.
VerDate Mar<15>2010
20:36 Apr 05, 2013
Jkt 229001
confidence. The total return that a
trading platform earns reflects the
revenues it receives from both products
and the joint costs it incurs. Moreover,
an exchange’s broker-dealer customers
view the costs of transaction executions
and market data as a unified cost of
doing business with the exchange.
Other market participants have noted
that the liquidity provided by the order
book, trade execution, core market data,
and non-core market data are joint
products of a joint platform and have
common costs.31 The Exchange agrees
with and adopts those discussions and
the arguments therein. The Exchange
also notes that the economics literature
confirms that there is no way to allocate
common costs between joint products
that would shed any light on
competitive or efficient pricing.32
Analyzing the cost of market data
product production and distribution in
isolation from the cost of all of the
inputs supporting the creation of market
data and market data products will
inevitably underestimate the cost of the
data and data products. Thus, because it
is impossible to obtain the data inputs
31 See Securities Exchange Act Release No. 62887
(Sept. 10, 2010), 75 FR 57092, 57095 (Sept. 17,
2010) (SR–Phlx–2010–121); Securities Exchange
Act Release No. 62907 (Sept. 14, 2010), 75 FR
57314, 57317 (Sept. 20, 2010) (SR–NASDAQ–2010–
110); and Securities Exchange Act Release No.
62908 (Sept. 14, 2010), 75 FR 57321, 57324 (Sept.
20, 2010) (SR–NASDAQ–2010–111) (‘‘all of the
exchange’s costs are incurred for the unified
purposes of attracting order flow, executing and/or
routing orders, and generating and selling data
about market activity. The total return that an
exchange earns reflects the revenues it receives
from the joint products and the total costs of the
joint products.’’); see also August 1, 2008 Comment
Letter of Jeffrey S. Davis, Vice President and Deputy
General Counsel, NASDAQ OMX Group, Inc.,
Statement of Janusz Ordover and Gustavo
Bamberger (‘‘because market data is both an input
to and a byproduct of executing trades on a
particular platform, market data and trade
execution services are an example of ‘joint
products’ with ‘joint costs.’ ’’), attachment at pg. 4,
available at www.sec.gov/comments/34-57917/
3457917-12.pdf.
32 See generally Mark Hirschey, Fundamentals of
Managerial Economics, at 600 (2009) (‘‘It is
important to note, however, that although it is
possible to determine the separate marginal costs of
goods produced in variable proportions, it is
impossible to determine their individual average
costs. This is because common costs are expenses
necessary for manufacture of a joint product.
Common costs of production—raw material and
equipment costs, management expenses, and other
overhead—cannot be allocated to each individual
by-product on any economically sound basis. * * *
Any allocation of common costs is wrong and
arbitrary.’’). This is not new economic theory. See,
e.g., F. W. Taussig, ‘‘A Contribution to the Theory
of Railway Rates,’’ Quarterly Journal of Economics
V(4) 438, 465 (July 1891) (‘‘Yet, surely, the division
is purely arbitrary. These items of cost, in fact, are
jointly incurred for both sorts of traffic; and I cannot
share the hope entertained by the statistician of the
Commission, Professor Henry C. Adams, that we
shall ever reach a mode of apportionment that will
lead to trustworthy results.’’).
PO 00000
Frm 00097
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
20979
to create market data products without
a fast, technologically robust, and wellregulated execution system, system
costs and regulatory costs affect the
price of both obtaining the market data
itself and creating and distributing
market data products. It would be
equally misleading, however, to
attribute all of an exchange’s costs to the
market data portion of an exchange’s
joint products. Rather, all of an
exchange’s costs are incurred for the
unified purposes of attracting order
flow, executing and/or routing orders,
and generating and selling data about
market activity. The total return that an
exchange earns reflects the revenues it
receives from the joint products and the
total costs of the joint products.
The level of competition and
contestability in the market is evident in
the numerous alternative venues that
compete for order flow, including 12
equities self-regulatory organization
(‘‘SRO’’) markets, as well as
internalizing broker-dealers (‘‘BDs’’) and
various forms of alternative trading
systems (‘‘ATSs’’), including dark pools
and electronic communication networks
(‘‘ECNs’’). Competition among trading
platforms can be expected to constrain
the aggregate return that each platform
earns from the sale of its joint products,
but different platforms may choose from
a range of possible, and equally
reasonable, pricing strategies as the
means of recovering total costs. For
example, some platforms may choose to
pay rebates to attract orders, charge
relatively low prices for market data
products (or provide market data
products free of charge), and charge
relatively high prices for accessing
posted liquidity. Other platforms may
choose a strategy of paying lower
rebates (or no rebates) to attract orders,
setting relatively high prices for market
data products, and setting relatively low
prices for accessing posted liquidity. In
this environment, there is no economic
basis for regulating maximum prices for
one of the joint products in an industry
in which suppliers face competitive
constraints with regard to the joint
offering.
Existence of Alternatives. The large
number of SROs, BDs, and ATSs that
currently produce proprietary data or
are currently capable of producing it
provides further pricing discipline for
proprietary data products. Each SRO,
ATS, and BD is currently permitted to
produce proprietary data products, and
many currently do or have announced
plans to do so, including but not limited
to the Exchange, NYSE MKT, NYSE
Arca, NASDAQ OMX, BATS, and Direct
Edge.
E:\FR\FM\08APN1.SGM
08APN1
20980
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 67 / Monday, April 8, 2013 / Notices
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
The fact that proprietary data from
ATSs, BDs, and vendors can bypass
SROs is significant in two respects.
First, non-SROs can compete directly
with SROs for the production and sale
of proprietary data products. Second,
because a single order or transaction
report can appear in an SRO proprietary
product, a non-SRO proprietary
product, or both, the amount of data
available via proprietary products is
greater in size than the actual number of
orders and transaction reports that exist
in the marketplace. Because market data
users can thus find suitable substitutes
for most proprietary market data
products,33 a market that overprices its
market data products stands a high risk
that users may substitute another source
of market data information for its own.
Those competitive pressures imposed
by available alternatives are evident in
the Exchange’s proposed pricing. As
noted above, the proposed non-display
fees for NYSE OpenBook, NYSE Trades,
and NYSE BBO are generally lower than
the maximum non-display fees charged
by other exchanges such as NASDAQ,
Phlx, and BX for comparable
products.34 The proposed redistribution
fee for NYSE OpenBook also is
comparable to the other exchanges’
similar fees.35
In addition to the competition and
price discipline described above, the
market for proprietary data products is
also highly contestable because market
entry is rapid and inexpensive. The
history of electronic trading is replete
with examples of entrants that swiftly
grew into some of the largest electronic
trading platforms and proprietary data
producers: Archipelago, Bloomberg
Tradebook, Island, RediBook, Attain,
TrackECN, BATS Trading and Direct
Edge. Today, BATS and Direct Edge
provide certain market data at no charge
on their Web sites in order to attract
more order flow, and use revenue
rebates from resulting additional
executions to maintain low execution
charges for their users.36
Further, data products are valuable to
certain end users only insofar as they
provide information that end users
expect will assist them or their
customers. The Exchange believes the
proposed non-display fees will benefit
customers by providing them with a
33 See
supra nn.19–22.
34 Id.
35 See
supra n.23.
is simply a securities market-specific
example of the well-established principle that in
certain circumstances more sales at lower margins
can be more profitable than fewer sales at higher
margins; this example is additional evidence that
market data is an inherent part of a market’s joint
platform.
36 This
VerDate Mar<15>2010
20:02 Apr 05, 2013
Jkt 229001
clearer way to determine their fee
liability for non-display devices, and
with respect to internal use, to obviate
the need to count such devices. The
Exchange further believes that only
vendors that expect to derive a
reasonable benefit from redistributing
the market data products described
herein will choose to become
Redistributors and pay the attendant
monthly fees.
In establishing the proposed fees, the
Exchange considered the
competitiveness of the market for
proprietary data and all of the
implications of that competition. The
Exchange believes that it has considered
all relevant factors and has not
considered irrelevant factors in order to
establish fair, reasonable, and not
unreasonably discriminatory fees and an
equitable allocation of fees among all
users. The existence of numerous
alternatives to the Exchange’s products,
including proprietary data from other
sources, ensures that the Exchange
cannot set unreasonable fees, or fees
that are unreasonably discriminatory,
when vendors and subscribers can elect
these alternatives or choose not to
purchase a specific proprietary data
product if its cost to purchase is not
justified by the returns any particular
vendor or subscriber would achieve
through the purchase.
C. Self-Regulatory Organization’s
Statement on Comments on the
Proposed Rule Change Received From
Members, Participants, or Others
The Exchange published draft Data
Policies on its Web site on November
20, 2012. Among other things, the Data
Policies addressed non-display use for
certain market data products. The
Exchange solicited comments on the
Data Policies in the form of a survey.
The Exchange received 14 comments
relating to non-display use. Exhibit 2
contains a copy of the notice soliciting
comment, the Data Policies, the 14
comments received in alphabetical
order, and an alphabetical listing of
such comments.
Nine commenters 37 requested greater
clarity with respect to the definition and
examples of non-display use.
Specifically, the commenters requested
that the Exchange provide a consistent
definition of non-display use. As
described above, the definition of nondisplay use will be accessing,
processing or consuming an NYSE data
product delivered via direct and/or
Redistributor data feeds, for a purpose
37 Barclays, Brown Brothers Harriman, CMC
Markets, Deutsche Bank, Flowtraders, Nomura,
Threadneedle, Transtrend BV, and UBS.
PO 00000
Frm 00098
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
other than in support of its display or
further internal or external
redistribution. The Exchange believes
that this definition addresses the
comments and will clearly describe the
types of activities that will qualify for
the proposed fee. The Exchange also
provided examples for illustrative
purposes, which are not exclusive.
Four commenters 38 also questioned
whether price referencing, compliance,
accounting or auditing activities, and
derived data should be considered nondisplay use. The Data Policies listed
price referencing, compliance,
accounting or auditing activities, and
derived data as examples of non-display
usage; however, as discussed above, the
Exchange has determined that price
referencing for the purposes of
algorithmic trading and/or smart order
routing would be considered NonDisplay Trading Activities, and
applications that use the data product
for non-trading activities, such as
compliance, accounting or auditing
activities, and derived data are not
covered by the non-display fees and are
subject to the current standard perdevice fee structure.
Three commenters 39 requested clarity
on the NYSE Unit-of-Count Policy for
non-display use. As discussed above,
the NYSE Unit-of-Count Policy will
continue to apply to Redistributors and
customers that have been approved
under the NYSE Unit-of Count Policy.
Under the proposed rule change, the
pricing structure for display usage will
remain the same. However, for nondisplay usage, customers approved
under the NYSE Unit-of-Count Policy
will be eligible for the managed nondisplay services at the managed nondisplay fee, which is offered either
directly from the Exchange or through a
Redistributor.
Two commenters 40 asked for more
detail on the managed non-display
service, which the Exchange has
provided above.
Three commenters 41 asked for
examples of how the Exchange would
charge for customers that use both
display and non-display devices. The
Exchange believes that the pricing
examples provided above are responsive
to this request. One commenter 42 stated
that the proposed fees are excessive.
The Exchange believes that the
proposed fees are reasonable, equitable,
38 Barclays, CMC Markets, Transtrend BV, and
UBS.
39 Barclays, Essex Radez LLC, and UBS.
40 FXCM and RTS Group.
41 Essex Radez LLC, Fidelity Market Data, and
Lloyds TSB Bank plc.
42 Essex Radez LLC.
E:\FR\FM\08APN1.SGM
08APN1
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 67 / Monday, April 8, 2013 / Notices
and not unfairly discriminatory for the
reasons discussed in Section 3(b) above.
III. Date of Effectiveness of the
Proposed Rule Change and Timing for
Commission Action
The foregoing rule change is effective
upon filing pursuant to Section
19(b)(3)(A) 43 of the Act and
subparagraph (f)(2) of Rule 19b–4 44
thereunder, because it establishes a due,
fee, or other charge imposed by the
Exchange.
At any time within 60 days of the
filing of such proposed rule change, the
Commission summarily may
temporarily suspend such rule change if
it appears to the Commission that such
action is necessary or appropriate in the
public interest, for the protection of
investors, or otherwise in furtherance of
the purposes of the Act. If the
Commission takes such action, the
Commission shall institute proceedings
under Section 19(b)(2)(B) 45 of the Act to
determine whether the proposed rule
change should be approved or
disapproved.
IV. Solicitation of Comments
Interested persons are invited to
submit written data, views, and
arguments concerning the foregoing,
including whether the proposed rule
change is consistent with the Act.
Comments may be submitted by any of
the following methods:
Electronic Comments
• Use the Commission’s Internet
comment form (https://www.sec.gov/
rules/sro.shtml); or
• Send an email to rulecomments@sec.gov. Please include File
Number SR–NYSE–2013–25 on the
subject line.
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
Paper Comments
• Send paper comments in triplicate
to Elizabeth M. Murphy, Secretary,
Securities and Exchange Commission,
100 F Street NE., Washington, DC
20549–1090.
All submissions should refer to File
Number SR–NYSE–2013–25. This file
number should be included on the
subject line if email is used. To help the
Commission process and review your
comments more efficiently, please use
only one method. The Commission will
post all comments on the Commission’s
Internet Web site (https://www.sec.gov/
rules/sro.shtml). Copies of the
submission, all subsequent
amendments, all written statements
U.S.C. 78s(b)(3)(A).
CFR 240.19b–4(f)(2).
45 15 U.S.C. 78s(b)(2)(B).
with respect to the proposed rule
change that are filed with the
Commission, and all written
communications relating to the
proposed rule change between the
Commission and any person, other than
those that may be withheld from the
public in accordance with the
provisions of 5 U.S.C. 552, will be
available for Web site viewing and
printing in the Commission’s Public
Reference Room, 100 F Street NE.,
Washington, DC 20549, on official
business days between the hours of
10:00 a.m. and 3:00 p.m. Copies of the
filing also will be available for
inspection and copying at the principal
office of the Exchange. All comments
received will be posted without change;
the Commission does not edit personal
identifying information from
submissions. You should submit only
information that you wish to make
available publicly. All submissions
should refer to File Number SR–NYSE–
2013–25 and should be submitted on or
before April 29, 2013.
For the Commission, by the Division of
Trading and Markets, pursuant to delegated
authority.46
Kevin M. O’Neill,
Deputy Secretary.
[FR Doc. 2013–08098 Filed 4–5–13; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 8011–01–P
SECURITIES AND EXCHANGE
COMMISSION
[Release No. 34–69269; File No. SR–Phlx–
2013–37]
Self-Regulatory Organizations;
NASDAQ OMX PHLX LLC; Notice of
Filing and Immediate Effectiveness of
Proposed Rule Change To Extend Its
FLEX Option No Minimum Value Size
Pilot Program to March 28, 2014
April 2, 2013.
Pursuant to Section 19(b)(1) of the
Securities Exchange Act of 1934
(‘‘Act’’) 1 and Rule 19b–4 thereunder,2
notice is hereby given that on March 27,
2013, NASDAQ OMX PHLX LLC
(‘‘Phlx’’ or ‘‘Exchange’’) filed with the
Securities and Exchange Commission
(‘‘SEC’’ or ‘‘Commission’’) the proposed
rule change as described in Items I and
II below, which Items have been
prepared by the Exchange. The
Commission is publishing this notice to
solicit comments on the proposed rule
change from interested persons.
43 15
46 17
44 17
1 15
VerDate Mar<15>2010
20:02 Apr 05, 2013
CFR 200.30–3(a)(12).
U.S.C. 78s(b)(1).
2 17 CFR 240.19b–4.
Jkt 229001
PO 00000
Frm 00099
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
20981
I. Self-Regulatory Organization’s
Statement of the Terms of Substance of
the Proposed Rule Change
The Exchange is filing with the
Commission a proposal to amend Phlx
Rule 1079 (FLEX Index, Equity and
Currency Options) to extend a pilot
program that eliminates minimum value
sizes for FLEX index options and FLEX
equity options (together known as
‘‘FLEX Options’’).3
The text of the amended Exchange
rule is set forth immediately below.
Additions are italicized and deletions
are [bracketed].
*
*
*
*
*
Rule 1079. FLEX Index, Equity and
Currency Options
A Requesting Member shall obtain
quotes and execute trades in certain
non-listed FLEX options at the specialist
post of the non-FLEX option on the
Exchange. The term ‘‘FLEX option’’
means a FLEX option contract that is
traded subject to this Rule. Although
FLEX options are generally subject to
the rules in this section, to the extent
that the provisions of this Rule are
inconsistent with other applicable
Exchange rules, this Rule takes
precedence with respect to FLEX
options.
(a)–(f) No Change.
* * * Commentary:
.01 Notwithstanding subparagraphs
(a)(8)(A)(i) and (a)(8)(A)(ii) above, for a
pilot period ending March [29]28,
[2013]2014, there shall be no minimum
value size requirements for FLEX
options.
*
*
*
*
*
The text of the proposed rule change
is available on the Exchange’s Web site
at https://
nasdaqomxphlx.cchwallstreet.com/
NASDAQOMXPHLX/Filings/, at the
principal office of the Exchange, and at
the Commission’s Public Reference
Room.
II. Self-Regulatory Organization’s
Statement of the Purpose of, and
Statutory Basis for, the Proposed Rule
Change
In its filing with the Commission, the
Exchange included statements
3 In addition to FLEX Options, FLEX currency
options are also traded on the Exchange. These
flexible index, equity, and currency options provide
investors the ability to customize basic option
features including size, expiration date, exercise
style, and certain exercise prices; and may have
expiration dates within five years. See Rule 1079.
FLEX currency options traded on the Exchange are
also known as FLEX World Currency Options
(‘‘WCO’’) or Foreign Currency Options (‘‘FCO’’).
The pilot program discussed herein does not
encompass FLEX currency options.
E:\FR\FM\08APN1.SGM
08APN1
Agencies
[Federal Register Volume 78, Number 67 (Monday, April 8, 2013)]
[Notices]
[Pages 20973-20981]
From the Federal Register Online via the Government Printing Office [www.gpo.gov]
[FR Doc No: 2013-08098]
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
SECURITIES AND EXCHANGE COMMISSION
[Release No. 34-69278; File No. SR-NYSE-2013-25]
Self-Regulatory Organizations; New York Stock Exchange LLC;
Notice of Filing and Immediate Effectiveness of Proposed Rule Change To
Establish Non-Display Usage Fees for NYSE OpenBook, NYSE Trades, and
NYSE BBO and a Redistribution Fee for NYSE OpenBook
April 2, 2013.
Pursuant to Section 19(b)(1) \1\ of the Securities Exchange Act of
1934 (the ``Act'') \2\ and Rule 19b-4 thereunder,\3\ notice is hereby
given that, on March 21, 2013, New York Stock Exchange LLC (``NYSE'' or
the ``Exchange'') filed with the Securities and Exchange Commission
(the ``Commission'') the proposed rule change as described in Items I,
II, and III below, which Items have been prepared by the self-
regulatory organization. The Commission is publishing this notice to
[[Page 20974]]
solicit comments on the proposed rule change from interested persons.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1\ 15 U.S.C. 78s(b)(1).
\2\ 15 U.S.C. 78a.
\3\ 17 CFR 240.19b-4.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
I. Self-Regulatory Organization's Statement of the Terms of Substance
of the Proposed Rule Change
The Exchange proposes to establish non-display usage fees for NYSE
OpenBook, NYSE Trades, and NYSE BBO and a redistribution fee for NYSE
OpenBook, all of which will be operative on April 1, 2013. The text of
the proposed rule change is available on the Exchange's Web site at
www.nyse.com, at the principal office of the Exchange, and at the
Commission's Public Reference Room.
II. Self-Regulatory Organization's Statement of the Purpose of, and
Statutory Basis for, the Proposed Rule Change
In its filing with the Commission, the self-regulatory organization
included statements concerning the purpose of, and basis for, the
proposed rule change and discussed any comments it received on the
proposed rule change. The text of those statements may be examined at
the places specified in Item IV below. The Exchange has prepared
summaries, set forth in sections A, B, and C below, of the most
significant parts of such statements.
A. Self-Regulatory Organization's Statement of the Purpose of, and the
Statutory Basis for, the Proposed Rule Change
1. Purpose
The Exchange proposes to establish non-display usage fees for NYSE
OpenBook, NYSE Trades, and NYSE BBO and a redistribution fee for NYSE
OpenBook, all of which will be operative on April 1, 2013. The
subsections below describe (1) the background on the current fees for
these real-time products; (2) the rationale for creating a new non-
display usage fee structure; (3) the proposed fees for non-display use,
which will include internal non-display use and managed non-display
use; (4) the proposed redistribution fee for NYSE OpenBook; (5)
examples comparing the current and proposed fees; and (6) a correction
to the Market Data Fee schedule.
Background on Current Fees
The current monthly fees for NYSE OpenBook,\4\ NYSE BBO,\5\ and
NYSE Trades \6\ are as follows:
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\4\ See Securities Exchange Act Release Nos. 59544 (Mar. 9,
2009), 74 FR 11162 (Mar. 16, 2009) (SR-NYSE-2008-131) and 62038 (May
5, 2010), 75 FR 26825 (May 12, 2010) (SR-NYSE-2010-22).
\5\ See Securities Exchange Act Release No. 62181 (May 26,
2010), 75 FR 31488 (June 3, 2010) (SR-NYSE-2010-30).
\6\ See SR-NYSE-2013-24.
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Digital Media
Product Access Fee Subscriber Fees Enterprise Fee Redistribution Fee
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
NYSE OpenBook \7\................ $5,000 Professional: $60 N/A................ N/A.
Non-professional:
$15 Non-
professional Fee
Cap: $25,000.
NYSE BBO......................... 1,500 Professional: $15 N/A................ N/A.
Non-professional:
$5.
NYSE Trades...................... \8\ 1,500 Professional: $15.. $40,000............ $1,000 (operative
May 1, 2013).
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
While the majority of subscribers pay the subscriber fee for each
display or non-display device that has access to the market data
products as set forth above, a small number of vendors and subscribers
are eligible for, and have elected, the NYSE Unit-of-Count Policy that
was first introduced as an NYSE OpenBook pilot in 2009 and is now also
available for NYSE BBO and NYSE Trades.\9\ Under this fee structure,
these vendors and subscribers are subject to a fee structure that
utilizes the following basic principles:
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\7\ The NYSE OpenBook Bundle pricing package includes: (i) NYSE
OpenBook Realtime, by which the Exchange makes NYSE OpenBook
Realtime available on a snapshot basis, with updates distributed in
real-time at intervals of one second; and (ii) NYSE OpenBook Ultra,
by which the Exchange updates NYSE OpenBook information upon receipt
of each displayed limit order, or upon an event that removes limit
orders from NYSE OpenBook (i.e., cancellation or execution). For no
additional charge, the Exchange makes available to recipients of
NYSE OpenBook additional data feeds containing NYSE BBO and Order
Imbalance Information. See Securities Exchange Act Release No. 59544
(Mar. 9, 2009), 74 FR 11162 (Mar. 16, 2009) (SR-NYSE-2008-131).
\8\ One $1,500 monthly access fee entitles a vendor to receive
both the NYSE BBO data feed as well as the Exchange's NYSE Trades
data feed. See supra n.5.
\9\ See Securities Exchange Act Release Nos. 62038 (May 5,
2010), 75 FR 26825 (May 12, 2010) (SR-NYSE-2010-22); 62181 (May 26,
2010), 75 FR 31488 (June 3, 2010) (SR-NYSE-2010-30); and 59290 (Jan.
23, 2009), 74 FR 5707 (Jan. 30, 2009) (SR-NYSE-2009-05).
i. Vendors.
``Vendors'' are market data vendors, broker-dealers,
private network providers, and other entities that control
Subscribers' access to a market data product through Subscriber
Entitlement Controls (as described below).
ii. Subscribers.
``Subscribers'' are unique individual persons or
devices (which include both display and non-display devices) to
which a Vendor provides a market data product. Any individual or
device that receives the market data product from a Vendor is a
Subscriber, whether the individual or device works for or belongs to
the Vendor, or works for or belongs to an entity other than the
Vendor.
Only a Vendor may control Subscriber access to the
market data product.
Subscribers may not redistribute the market data
product in any manner.
iii. Subscriber Entitlements.
A Subscriber Entitlement is a Vendor's permitting a
Subscriber to receive access to the market data product through an
Exchange-approved Subscriber Entitlement Control.
A Vendor may not provide access to a market data
product to a Subscriber except through a unique Subscriber
Entitlement.
The Exchange will require each Vendor to provide a
unique Subscriber Entitlement to each unique Subscriber.
At prescribed intervals (normally monthly), the
Exchange will require each Vendor to report each unique Subscriber
Entitlement.
iv. Subscriber Entitlement Controls.
A Subscriber Entitlement Control is the Vendor's
process of permitting Subscribers' access to a market data product.
Prior to using any Subscriber Entitlement Control or
changing a previously approved Subscriber Entitlement Control, a
Vendor must provide the Exchange with a demonstration and a detailed
written description of the control or change and the Exchange must
have approved it in writing.
The Exchange will approve a Subscriber Entitlement
Control if it allows only authorized, unique end-users or devices to
access the market data product or monitors access to the market data
product by each unique end-user or device.
Vendors must design Subscriber Entitlement Controls to
produce an audit report and make each audit report available to the
Exchange upon request. The audit report must identify:
Each entitlement update to the Subscriber Entitlement
Control;
[[Page 20975]]
The status of the Subscriber Entitlement Control; and
Any other changes to the Subscriber Entitlement Control
over a given period.
Only the Vendor may have access to Subscriber
Entitlement Controls.
Vendors must count every Subscriber Entitlement, whether it be an
individual person or a device. Thus, the Vendor's count would include
every person and device that accesses the data regardless of the
purpose for which the individual or device uses the data.
Vendors must report all Subscriber Entitlements in accordance with
the following:
i. In connection with a Vendor's external distribution of the
market data product, the Vendor should count as one Subscriber
Entitlement each unique Subscriber that the Vendor has entitled to have
access to the market data product. However, where a device is dedicated
specifically to a single individual, the Vendor should count only the
individual and need not count the device.
ii. In connection with a Vendor's internal distribution of a market
data product, the Vendor should count as one Subscriber Entitlement
each unique individual (but not devices) that the Vendor has entitled
to have access to such market data.
iii. The Vendor should identify and report each unique Subscriber.
If a Subscriber uses the same unique Subscriber Entitlement to gain
access to multiple market data services, the Vendor should count that
as one Subscriber Entitlement. However, if a unique Subscriber uses
multiple Subscriber Entitlements to gain access to one or more market
data services (e.g., a single Subscriber has multiple passwords and
user identifications), the Vendor should report all of those Subscriber
Entitlements.
iv. Vendors should report each unique individual person who
receives access through multiple devices as one Subscriber Entitlement
so long as each device is dedicated specifically to that individual.
v. The Vendor should include in the count as one Subscriber
Entitlement devices serving no entitled individuals. However, if the
Vendor entitles one or more individuals to use the same device, the
Vendor should include only the entitled individuals, and not the
device, in the count.
Rationale for New Non-Display Usage Fee Structure
As noted in the original NYSE Unit-of-Count Policy proposal,
``technology has made it increasingly difficult to define `device' and
to control who has access to devices, [and] the markets have struggled
to make device counts uniform among their customers.'' \10\ Significant
change has characterized the industry in recent years, stemming in
large measure from changes in regulation and technological advances,
which has led to the rise in automated and algorithmic trading.
Additionally, market data feeds have become faster and contain a vastly
larger number of quotes and trades. Today, a majority of trading is
done by leveraging non-display devices consuming massive amounts of
data. Some firms base their business models largely on incorporating
non-display data into applications and do not require widespread data
access by the firm's employees. Changes in market data consumption
patterns have increased the use and importance of non-display data.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\10\ See Securities Exchange Act Release No. 59544 (Mar. 9,
2009), 74 FR 11162 (Mar. 16, 2009) (SR-NYSE-2008-131). At least one
other Exchange also has noted such administrative challenges. In
establishing a non-display usage fee for internal distributors of
TotalView and OpenView, NASDAQ Stock Market LLC (``NASDAQ'') noted
that as ``the number of devices increase, so does the administrative
burden on the end customer of counting these devices.'' See
Securities Exchange Act Release No. 61700 (Mar. 12, 2010), 75 FR
13172 (Mar. 18, 2010) (SR-NASDAQ-2010-034).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Applications that can be used in non-display devices provide added
value in their capability to manipulate and spread the data they
consume. Such applications have the ability to perform calculations on
the live data stream and manufacture new data out of it. Data can be
processed much faster by a non-display device than it can be by a human
being processing information that he or she views on a data terminal.
Non-display devices also can dispense data to multiple computer
applications as compared with the restriction of data to one display
terminal.
While the non-display data has become increasingly valuable to data
recipients who can use it to generate substantial profits, it has
become increasing difficult for them and the Exchange to accurately
count non-display devices. The number and type of non-display devices,
as well as their complexity and interconnectedness, have grown in
recent years, creating administrative challenges for vendors, data
recipients, and the Exchange to accurately count such devices and audit
such counts. Unlike a display device, such as a Bloomberg terminal, it
is not possible to simply walk through a trading floor or areas of a
data recipient's premises to identify non-display devices. During an
audit, an auditor must review a firm's entitlement report to determine
usage. While display use is generally associated with an individual end
user and/or unique user ID, a non-display use is more difficult to
account for because the entitlement report may show a server name or
Internet protocol (``IP'') address or it may not. The auditor must
review each IP or server and further inquire about downstream use and
quantity of servers with access to data; this type of counting is very
labor-intensive and prone to inaccuracies.
For these reasons, the Exchange determined that its current fee
structure, which is based on counting non-display devices, is no longer
appropriate in light of market and technology developments and does not
reflect the value of the non-display data and its many profit-
generating uses for subscribers. As such, the Exchange, in conjunction
with its domestic and foreign affiliate exchanges, undertook a review
of its market data policies with a goal of bringing greater consistency
and clarity to its fee structure; easing administration for itself,
vendors, and subscribers; and setting fees at a level that better
reflects the current value of the data provided. As a result of this
review, the Exchange has determined to offer a new fee structure for
display and non-display use of certain market data products. Initially,
the Exchange will implement the new non-display use fee structure for
NYSE OpenBook, NYSE BBO, and NYSE Trades, operative on April 1, 2013.
The Exchange anticipates implementing a new display use fee structure
later this year; until such time, existing fees for display use will
apply.
Proposed Non-Display Usage Fees
The Exchange proposes to establish new monthly fees for non-display
usage, which for purposes of the proposed fee structure will mean
accessing, processing or consuming an NYSE data product delivered via
direct and/or Redistributor \11\ data feeds, for a purpose other than
in support of its display or further internal or external
redistribution. The proposed non-display fees will apply to the non-
display use of the data product as part of automated calculations or
algorithms to support trading decision-making processes or the
operation of trading platforms (``Non-Display Trading Activities'').
They include, but are not limited to, high frequency trading, automated
order or quote generation and/or order pegging, or price
[[Page 20976]]
referencing for the purposes of algorithmic trading and/or smart order
routing. Applications and devices that solely facilitate display,
internal distribution, or redistribution of the data product with no
other uses and applications that use the data product for other non-
trading activities, such as the creation of derived data, quantitative
analysis, fund administration, portfolio management, and compliance,
are not covered by the proposed non-display fee structure and are
subject to the current standard per-device fee structure. The Exchange
reserves the right to audit data recipients' use of NYSE market data
products in Non-Display Trading Activities in accordance with NYSE's
vendor and subscriber agreements.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\11\ ``Redistributor'' means a vendor or any other person that
provides an NYSE data product to a data recipient or to any system
that a data recipient uses, irrespective of the means of
transmission or access.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
There will be two types of fees, which are described below. The
first type of fee is for internal non-display use. The second type of
fee is for managed non-display services. The current NYSE Unit-of-Count
Policy will no longer apply to any non-display usage.\12\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\12\ Existing customers that are approved for the NYSE Unit-of-
Count Policy for display usage may continue to follow that Policy
until the new display fees are implemented.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Proposed Fees for Internal Non-Display Use
The proposed internal non-display use fees will apply to NYSE
OpenBook, NYSE BBO, and NYSE Trades. Internal non-display use occurs
when a data recipient either manages its own non-display infrastructure
and controls the access to and permissioning of the market data product
on its non-display applications or when the data recipient's non-
display applications are hosted by a third party that has not been
approved to provide the managed non-display services as described
below.
The fee structure will have three categories, which recognize the
different uses for the market data. Category 1 Fees apply where a data
recipient's non-display use of real time market data is for the purpose
of principal trading. Category 2 Fees apply where a data recipient's
non-display use of market data is for the purpose of broker/agency
trading, i.e., trading-based activities to facilitate the recipient's
customers' business. If a data recipient trades both on a principal and
agency basis, then the data recipient must pay both categories of fees.
Category 3 Fees apply where a data recipient's non-display use of
market data is, in whole or in part, for the purpose of providing
reference prices in the operation of one or more trading platforms,
including but not limited to multilateral trading facilities,
alternative trading systems, broker crossing networks, dark pools, and
systematic internalization systems. A data recipient will not be liable
for Category 3 Fees for those market data products for which it is also
paying Category 1 and/or Category 2 Fees.
The fees for internal non-display use per data recipient
organization for each category will be as follows:
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Category 1 Category 2 Category 3
trading as trading as trading
Product principal broker/agency platform (per
(per month) (per month) month)
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
NYSE OpenBook................................................... $5,000 $5,000 $5,000
NYSE BBO........................................................ 1,500 1,500 1,500
NYSE Trades..................................................... 2,000 2,000 2,000
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Subscribers to NYSE OpenBook, which includes access to NYSE BBO and
NYSE Order Imbalances, are not required to subscribe to these two
individual services as part of the non-display activity for these
products.\13\ Subscribers who are not currently subscribing to NYSE
OpenBook Bundle pricing package \14\ will be responsible for the
individual product licenses for the non-display activity.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\13\ There is currently a $500/month access fee for the NYSE
Order Imbalances data feed.
\14\ See supra n.7
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
For internal non-display use, there will be no reporting
requirements regarding non-display device counts, thus doing away with
the administrative burdens described above. Data recipients will be
required to declare the market data products used within their non-
display trading applications by executing an NYSE Euronext Non-Display
Usage Declaration.
Proposed Fees for Managed Non-Display Services
The Exchange also proposes to establish fees for managed non-
display services for NYSE OpenBook and NYSE Trades. Under the managed
non-display service, a data recipient's non-display applications must
be hosted by a Redistributor approved by the Exchange, and this
Redistributor must manage and control the access to NYSE OpenBook and/
or NYSE Trades for these applications and may not allow for further
internal distribution or external redistribution of these market data
products. The Redistributor of the managed non-display services and the
data recipient must be approved under the current NYSE Unit-of-Count
policy described above,\15\ which will no longer be available for non-
display use after the proposed fees are implemented. If a data
recipient is receiving NYSE OpenBook and/or NYSE Trades for Non-Display
Trading Activities from a Redistributor that is not approved under the
NYSE Unit-of-Count policy, then the internal non-display fees described
above will apply.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\15\ See supra n.9.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The fees for managed non-display services per data recipient
organization will be as follows:
------------------------------------------------------------------------
Managed non-
display use
Product fee (per
month)
------------------------------------------------------------------------
NYSE OpenBook........................................... $2,000
NYSE Trades............................................. 700
------------------------------------------------------------------------
Data recipients will not be liable for managed non-display fees for
those market data products for which they pay the internal non-display
fee.
Upon request, a Redistributor offering managed non-display services
must provide the Exchange with a list of data recipients that are
receiving NYSE OpenBook or NYSE Trades through the Redistributor's
managed non-display service. Data recipients of the managed non-display
service have no additional reporting requirements, thus easing the
administrative burdens described above.
NYSE OpenBook Redistribution Fee
The Exchange proposes to establish a monthly redistribution fee of
$3,000 for NYSE OpenBook. The Exchange believes that it is reasonable
to charge this redistribution fee because vendors receive value from
redistributing the
[[Page 20977]]
data in their business products for their customers.
Examples
Broker-Dealer A obtains NYSE OpenBook directly from the Exchange
for internal use and does not fall under the NYSE Unit-of-Count Policy.
Broker-Dealer A trades both on a principal and agency basis and has (i)
80 individual persons who use 100 display devices and (ii) 50 non-
display devices.
Under the current fee schedule, Broker-Dealer A pays the
Exchange the $5,000 access fee plus $60 for each of the 100 display
devices (although 80 individual persons use them, the number of devices
is counted), or $6,000, and $60 for each of the 50 non-display devices,
or $3,000, for a total of $14,000 per month.
Under the proposed fee schedule, Broker-Dealer A would pay
the Exchange the $5,000 access fee plus $60 for each of the 100 display
devices, or $6,000, and Category 1 and Category 2 fees for internal
non-display use, or $10,000, for a total of $21,000 per month. No
redistribution fee would be charged.
Broker-Dealer B, which only trades as principal, obtains NYSE
OpenBook from Vendor X. Broker-Dealer B and Vendor X are both approved
for the NYSE Unit-of-Count Policy. Broker-Dealer B has (i) 10
individual persons who use 12 display devices and (ii) 5 non-display
devices.
Under the current fee schedule, Vendor X pays the $5,000
access fee and Broker-Dealer B pays $900 ($60 for the 10 individual
persons (under the NYSE Unit-of-Count Policy, the larger number of
display devices is not counted), or $600, plus $60 for each of the 5
non-display devices, or $300).
Under the proposed fee schedule, Broker-Dealer B would pay
$600 as it does today for its individual persons using display devices,
and $2,000 for managed non-display use, for a total of $2,600 per month
in fees. Vendor X would pay the $5,000 access fee and the $3,000
redistribution fee, for a total of $8,000 per month.
Correction to Market Data Fee Schedule
The Exchange recently created a Market Data Fee Schedule. The
Exchange proposes to correct the subscriber fee line for NYSE Trades to
reflect that there is only a professional subscriber fee and no non-
professional subscriber fee.\16\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\16\ See Securities Exchange Act Release No. 59309 (Jan. 28,
2009) 74 FR 6073 (Feb. 4, 2009) (SR-NYSE-2009-04).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
2. Statutory Basis
The Exchange believes that the proposed rule change is consistent
with the provisions of Section 6 of the Act,\17\ in general, and
Sections 6(b)(4) and 6(b)(5) of the Act,\18\ in particular, in that it
provides an equitable allocation of reasonable fees among users and
recipients of the data and is not designed to permit unfair
discrimination among customers, issuers, and brokers.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\17\ 15 U.S.C. 78f(b).
\18\ 15 U.S.C. 78f(b)(4), (5).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
As described in detail in the section ``Rationale for New Non-
Display Usage Fee Structure'' above, which is incorporated by reference
herein, technology has made it increasingly difficult to define
``device'' and to control who has access to devices. Significant change
has characterized the industry in recent years, stemming in large
measure from changes in regulation and technological advances, which
has led to the rise in automated and algorithmic trading, which have
the potential to generate substantial profits. Indeed, data used in a
single non-display device running a single trading algorithm can
generate large profits. Market data technology and usage has evolved to
the point where it is no longer practical, nor fair and equitable, to
simply count non-display devices. The administrative costs and
difficulties of establishing reliable counts and conducting an
effective audit of non-display devices have become too burdensome,
impractical, and non-economic for the Exchange, vendors, and data
recipients. Rather, the Exchange believes that its proposed flat fee
structure for non-display use is reasonable, equitable, and not
unfairly discriminatory in light of these developments.
Other exchanges also have established differentiated fees based on
non-display usage, including a flat or enterprise fee. For example,
NASDAQ professional subscribers pay monthly fees for non-display usage
based upon direct access to NASDAQ Level 2, NASDAQ TotalView, or NASDAQ
OpenView, which range from $300 per month for customers with one to 10
subscribers to $75,000 for customers with 250 or more subscribers.\19\
In addition, NASDAQ OMX PHLX, Inc. (``Phlx'') offers an alternative
$10,000 per month ``Non-Display Enterprise License'' fee that permits
distribution to an unlimited number of internal non-display subscribers
without incurring additional fees for each internal subscriber.\20\ The
Non-Display Enterprise License covers non-display subscriber fees for
all Phlx proprietary direct data feed products and is in addition to
any other associated distributor fees for Phlx proprietary direct data
feed products. NASDAQ OMX BX, Inc. (``BX'') also offers an alternative
non-display usage fee of $16,000 for its BX TotalView data feed.\21\
NASDAQ and Phlx also both offer managed non-display data solutions at
higher overall fees than the Exchange proposes to charge.\22\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\19\ See NASDAQ Rule 7023(b)(4).
\20\ See Securities Exchange Act Release No. 68576 (Jan. 3,
2013), 78 FR 1886 (Jan. 9, 2013) (SR-Phlx-2012-145). Alternatively,
Phlx charges each professional subscriber $40 per month.
\21\ See NASDAQ OMX BX Rule 7023(a)(2). Alternatively, BX
charges each professional subscriber $40 per month.
\22\ NASDAQ established fees for a Managed Data Solution to
Distributors, which includes a monthly Managed Data Solution
Administration fee of $1,500 and monthly Subscriber fees ranging
from $60 to $300. See NASDAQ Rule 7026(b). Phlx also established a
Managed Data Solution, which includes a monthly Managed Data
Solution Administration fee of $1,500 and a monthly Subscriber fee
of $250. The monthly License fee is in addition to Phlx's monthly
Distributor fee of $2,500 (for external usage), and the $250 monthly
Subscriber fee is assessed for each Subscriber of a Managed Data
Solution. See Securities Exchange Act Release No. 67466 (July 19,
2012), 77 FR 43629 (July 25, 2012) (SR-Phlx-2012-93).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The Exchange also believes that it is reasonable, equitable, and
not unfairly discriminatory to charge relatively lower fees for managed
non-display services because the Exchange expects that they will
generally be used by a small number of Redistributors and data
recipients that are currently eligible for the NYSE Unit-of-Count
Policy. These data recipients are constrained by whatever applications
are available via Redistributors operating in the Exchange's co-
location center and other hosted facilities. In comparison, a data
recipient that elects internal non-display use is free to use the data
in any manner it chooses and create new uses in an unlimited number of
non-display devices. The lack of constraint in this regard will make
the non-display usage of the data more valuable to such an internal use
data recipient.
The proposed redistribution fee for NYSE OpenBook also is
reasonable because it is comparable to other redistribution fees that
are currently charged by other exchanges.\23\ As noted
[[Page 20978]]
above, the Exchange believes that it is reasonable to charge
redistribution fees because vendors receive value from redistributing
the data in their business products for their customers. The
redistribution fees also are equitable and not unfairly discriminatory
because they will be charged on an equal basis to those vendors that
choose to redistribute the data.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\23\ NYSE Arca, Inc. (``NYSE Arca'') charges a $3,000 per month
redistribution fee for the NYSE Arca Integrated Feed, which includes
depth-of-book data. See Securities Exchange Act Release No. 66128
(Jan. 10, 2012), 77 FR 2331 (Jan. 17, 2012) (SR-NYSEArca-2011-96).
In addition, NYSE Arca and NYSE MKT LLC (``NYSE MKT'') charge
redistribution fees of $2,000 per month for certain proprietary
options market data products. See Securities Exchange Act Release
Nos. 68005 (Oct. 9, 2012), 77 FR 63362 (Oct. 16, 2012) (SR-NYSEArca-
2012-106), and 68004 (Oct. 9, 2012), 77 FR 62582 (Oct. 15, 2012)
(SR-NYSEMKT-2012-49). All distributors of a NASDAQ Last Sale Data
Feed also pay a monthly fee of $1,500. See NASDAQ Rule 7039(d).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The Exchange has not recently raised the market data fees for these
three proprietary products. The Exchange set the NYSE OpenBook
professional subscriber fee at $60 per device in 2006, the NYSE Trades
subscriber fee at $15 per device in 2009, and the NYSE BBO professional
subscriber fee at $15 per device in 2010.\24\ The Exchange believes
that the new fee schedule, which may result in certain vendors and data
recipients paying more than they have in the last several years, is
fair and reasonable in light of market and technology developments. The
current per-device fee structure no longer reflects the significant
overall value that non-display data can provide in trading algorithms
and other uses that provide professional users with the potential to
generate substantial profits. The Exchange believes that it is
equitable and not unfairly discriminatory to establish an overall
monthly fee that better reflects the value of the data to the data
recipients in their profit-generating activities and does away with the
burden of counting non-display devices.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\24\ See Securities Exchange Act Release Nos. 53585 (March 31,
2006), 71 FR 17934 (April 7, 2006) (SR-NYSE-2004-43 and SR-NYSE-
2005-32); 59606 (Mar. 19, 2009), 74 FR 13293 (Mar. 26, 2009) (SR-
NYSE-2009-04); and 62181 (May 26, 2010), 75 FR 31488 (June 3, 2010)
(SR-NYSE-2010-30).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The Exchange also notes that products described herein are entirely
optional. Firms are not required to purchase NYSE OpenBook, NYSE BBO,
or NYSE Trades. Firms have a wide variety of alternative market data
products from which to choose.\25\ Moreover, the Exchange is not
required to make these proprietary data products available or to offer
any specific pricing alternatives to any customers.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\25\ See supra nn.19-22.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The decision of the United States Court of Appeals for the District
of Columbia Circuit in NetCoalition v. SEC, 615 F.3d 525 (D.C. Cir.
2010), upheld reliance by the Securities and Exchange Commission
(``Commission'') upon the existence of competitive market mechanisms to
set reasonable and equitably allocated fees for proprietary market
data:
In fact, the legislative history indicates that the Congress
intended that the market system `evolve through the interplay of
competitive forces as unnecessary regulatory restrictions are removed'
and that the SEC wield its regulatory power `in those situations where
competition may not be sufficient,' such as in the creation of a
`consolidated transactional reporting system.'
Id. at 535 (quoting H.R. Rep. No. 94-229 at 92 (1975), as reprinted
in 1975 U.S.C.C.A.N. 323). The court agreed with the Commission's
conclusion that ``Congress intended that `competitive forces should
dictate the services and practices that constitute the U.S. national
market system for trading equity securities.' '' \26\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\26\ NetCoalition, 615 F.3d at 535.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
As explained below in the Exchange's Statement on Burden on
Competition, the Exchange believes that there is substantial evidence
of competition in the marketplace for data and that the Commission can
rely upon such evidence in concluding that the fees established in this
filing are the product of competition and therefore satisfy the
relevant statutory standards.\27\ In addition, the existence of
alternatives to these data products, such as proprietary last sale data
from other sources, as described below, further ensures that the
Exchange cannot set unreasonable fees, or fees that are unreasonably
discriminatory, when vendors and subscribers can elect such
alternatives.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\27\ Section 916 of the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and
Consumer Protection Act of 2010 (the ``Dodd-Frank Act'') amended
paragraph (A) of Section 19(b)(3) of the Act, 15 U.S.C. 78s(b)(3),
to make clear that all exchange fees for market data may be filed by
exchanges on an immediately effective basis.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
As the NetCoalition decision noted, the Commission is not required
to undertake a cost-of-service or ratemaking approach, and the Exchange
incorporates by reference into this proposed rule change its
affiliate's analysis of this topic in another rule filing.\28\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\28\ See Securities Exchange Act Release No. 63291 (Nov. 9,
2010), 75 FR 70311 (Nov. 17, 2010) (SR-NYSEArca-2010-97).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
For these reasons, the Exchange believes that the proposed fees are
reasonable, equitable, and not unfairly discriminatory.
B. Self-Regulatory Organization's Statement on Burden on Competition
The Exchange does not believe that the proposed rule change will
impose any burden on competition that is not necessary or appropriate
in furtherance of the purposes of the Act. An exchange's ability to
price its proprietary data feed products is constrained by actual
competition for the sale of proprietary market data products, the joint
product nature of exchange platforms, and the existence of alternatives
to the Exchange's proprietary last sale data.
The Existence of Actual Competition. The market for proprietary
data products is currently competitive and inherently contestable
because there is fierce competition for the inputs necessary for the
creation of proprietary data and strict pricing discipline for the
proprietary products themselves. Numerous exchanges compete with each
other for listings and order flow and sales of market data itself,
providing virtually limitless opportunities for entrepreneurs who wish
to compete in any or all of those areas, including producing and
distributing their own market data. Proprietary data products are
produced and distributed by each individual exchange, as well as other
entities, in a vigorously competitive market.
Competitive markets for listings, order flow, executions, and
transaction reports provide pricing discipline for the inputs of
proprietary data products and therefore constrain markets from
overpricing proprietary market data. The U.S. Department of Justice
also has acknowledged the aggressive competition among exchanges,
including for the sale of proprietary market data itself. In announcing
that the bid for NYSE Euronext by NASDAQ OMX Group Inc. and
IntercontinentalExchange Inc. had been abandoned, Assistant Attorney
General Christine Varney stated that exchanges ``compete head to head
to offer real-time equity data products. These data products include
the best bid and offer of every exchange and information on each equity
trade, including the last sale.'' \29\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\29\ Press Release, U.S. Department of Justice, Assistant
Attorney General Christine Varney Holds Conference Call Regarding
NASDAQ OMX Group Inc. and IntercontinentalExchange Inc. Abandoning
Their Bid for NYSE Euronext (May 16, 2011), available at https://www.justice.gov/iso/opa/atr/speeches/2011/at-speech-110516.html.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
It is common for broker-dealers to further exploit this recognized
competitive constraint by sending their order flow and transaction
reports to multiple markets, rather than providing them all to a single
market. As a 2010 Commission Concept Release noted, the ``current
market structure can be described as dispersed and complex''
[[Page 20979]]
with ``trading volume * * * dispersed among many highly automated
trading centers that compete for order flow in the same stocks'' and
``trading centers offer[ing] a wide range of services that are designed
to attract different types of market participants with varying trading
needs.'' \30\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\30\ Concept Release on Equity Market Structure, Securities
Exchange Act Release No. 61358 (Jan. 14, 2010), 75 FR 3594 (Jan. 21,
2010) (File No. S7-02-10). This Concept Release included data from
the third quarter of 2009 showing that no market center traded more
than 20% of the volume of listed stocks, further evidencing the
dispersal of and competition for trading activity. Id. at 3598.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
In addition, in the case of products that are distributed through
market data vendors, the market data vendors themselves provide
additional price discipline for proprietary data products because they
control the primary means of access to certain end users. These vendors
impose price discipline based upon their business models. For example,
vendors that assess a surcharge on data they sell are able to refuse to
offer proprietary products that their end users do not or will not
purchase in sufficient numbers. Internet portals, such as Google,
impose price discipline by providing only data that they believe will
enable them to attract ``eyeballs'' that contribute to their
advertising revenue. Similarly, vendors will not elect to make
available the NYSE products described herein unless their customers
request them, and customers will not elect to purchase them unless they
can be used for profit-generating purposes. All of these operate as
constraints on pricing proprietary data products.
Joint Product Nature of Exchange Platform. Transaction execution
and proprietary data products are complementary in that market data is
both an input and a byproduct of the execution service. In fact, market
data and trade executions are a paradigmatic example of joint products
with joint costs. The decision whether and on which platform to post an
order will depend on the attributes of the platforms where the order
can be posted, including the execution fees, data quality, and price
and distribution of their data products. The more trade executions a
platform does, the more valuable its market data products become.
The costs of producing market data include not only the costs of
the data distribution infrastructure, but also the costs of designing,
maintaining, and operating the exchange's transaction execution
platform and the cost of regulating the exchange to ensure its fair
operation and maintain investor confidence. The total return that a
trading platform earns reflects the revenues it receives from both
products and the joint costs it incurs. Moreover, an exchange's broker-
dealer customers view the costs of transaction executions and market
data as a unified cost of doing business with the exchange.
Other market participants have noted that the liquidity provided by
the order book, trade execution, core market data, and non-core market
data are joint products of a joint platform and have common costs.\31\
The Exchange agrees with and adopts those discussions and the arguments
therein. The Exchange also notes that the economics literature confirms
that there is no way to allocate common costs between joint products
that would shed any light on competitive or efficient pricing.\32\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\31\ See Securities Exchange Act Release No. 62887 (Sept. 10,
2010), 75 FR 57092, 57095 (Sept. 17, 2010) (SR-Phlx-2010-121);
Securities Exchange Act Release No. 62907 (Sept. 14, 2010), 75 FR
57314, 57317 (Sept. 20, 2010) (SR-NASDAQ-2010-110); and Securities
Exchange Act Release No. 62908 (Sept. 14, 2010), 75 FR 57321, 57324
(Sept. 20, 2010) (SR-NASDAQ-2010-111) (``all of the exchange's costs
are incurred for the unified purposes of attracting order flow,
executing and/or routing orders, and generating and selling data
about market activity. The total return that an exchange earns
reflects the revenues it receives from the joint products and the
total costs of the joint products.''); see also August 1, 2008
Comment Letter of Jeffrey S. Davis, Vice President and Deputy
General Counsel, NASDAQ OMX Group, Inc., Statement of Janusz Ordover
and Gustavo Bamberger (``because market data is both an input to and
a byproduct of executing trades on a particular platform, market
data and trade execution services are an example of `joint products'
with `joint costs.' ''), attachment at pg. 4, available at
www.sec.gov/comments/34-57917/3457917-12.pdf.
\32\ See generally Mark Hirschey, Fundamentals of Managerial
Economics, at 600 (2009) (``It is important to note, however, that
although it is possible to determine the separate marginal costs of
goods produced in variable proportions, it is impossible to
determine their individual average costs. This is because common
costs are expenses necessary for manufacture of a joint product.
Common costs of production--raw material and equipment costs,
management expenses, and other overhead--cannot be allocated to each
individual by-product on any economically sound basis. * * * Any
allocation of common costs is wrong and arbitrary.''). This is not
new economic theory. See, e.g., F. W. Taussig, ``A Contribution to
the Theory of Railway Rates,'' Quarterly Journal of Economics V(4)
438, 465 (July 1891) (``Yet, surely, the division is purely
arbitrary. These items of cost, in fact, are jointly incurred for
both sorts of traffic; and I cannot share the hope entertained by
the statistician of the Commission, Professor Henry C. Adams, that
we shall ever reach a mode of apportionment that will lead to
trustworthy results.'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Analyzing the cost of market data product production and
distribution in isolation from the cost of all of the inputs supporting
the creation of market data and market data products will inevitably
underestimate the cost of the data and data products. Thus, because it
is impossible to obtain the data inputs to create market data products
without a fast, technologically robust, and well-regulated execution
system, system costs and regulatory costs affect the price of both
obtaining the market data itself and creating and distributing market
data products. It would be equally misleading, however, to attribute
all of an exchange's costs to the market data portion of an exchange's
joint products. Rather, all of an exchange's costs are incurred for the
unified purposes of attracting order flow, executing and/or routing
orders, and generating and selling data about market activity. The
total return that an exchange earns reflects the revenues it receives
from the joint products and the total costs of the joint products.
The level of competition and contestability in the market is
evident in the numerous alternative venues that compete for order flow,
including 12 equities self-regulatory organization (``SRO'') markets,
as well as internalizing broker-dealers (``BDs'') and various forms of
alternative trading systems (``ATSs''), including dark pools and
electronic communication networks (``ECNs''). Competition among trading
platforms can be expected to constrain the aggregate return that each
platform earns from the sale of its joint products, but different
platforms may choose from a range of possible, and equally reasonable,
pricing strategies as the means of recovering total costs. For example,
some platforms may choose to pay rebates to attract orders, charge
relatively low prices for market data products (or provide market data
products free of charge), and charge relatively high prices for
accessing posted liquidity. Other platforms may choose a strategy of
paying lower rebates (or no rebates) to attract orders, setting
relatively high prices for market data products, and setting relatively
low prices for accessing posted liquidity. In this environment, there
is no economic basis for regulating maximum prices for one of the joint
products in an industry in which suppliers face competitive constraints
with regard to the joint offering.
Existence of Alternatives. The large number of SROs, BDs, and ATSs
that currently produce proprietary data or are currently capable of
producing it provides further pricing discipline for proprietary data
products. Each SRO, ATS, and BD is currently permitted to produce
proprietary data products, and many currently do or have announced
plans to do so, including but not limited to the Exchange, NYSE MKT,
NYSE Arca, NASDAQ OMX, BATS, and Direct Edge.
[[Page 20980]]
The fact that proprietary data from ATSs, BDs, and vendors can
bypass SROs is significant in two respects. First, non-SROs can compete
directly with SROs for the production and sale of proprietary data
products. Second, because a single order or transaction report can
appear in an SRO proprietary product, a non-SRO proprietary product, or
both, the amount of data available via proprietary products is greater
in size than the actual number of orders and transaction reports that
exist in the marketplace. Because market data users can thus find
suitable substitutes for most proprietary market data products,\33\ a
market that overprices its market data products stands a high risk that
users may substitute another source of market data information for its
own.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\33\ See supra nn.19-22.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Those competitive pressures imposed by available alternatives are
evident in the Exchange's proposed pricing. As noted above, the
proposed non-display fees for NYSE OpenBook, NYSE Trades, and NYSE BBO
are generally lower than the maximum non-display fees charged by other
exchanges such as NASDAQ, Phlx, and BX for comparable products.\34\ The
proposed redistribution fee for NYSE OpenBook also is comparable to the
other exchanges' similar fees.\35\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\34\ Id.
\35\ See supra n.23.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
In addition to the competition and price discipline described
above, the market for proprietary data products is also highly
contestable because market entry is rapid and inexpensive. The history
of electronic trading is replete with examples of entrants that swiftly
grew into some of the largest electronic trading platforms and
proprietary data producers: Archipelago, Bloomberg Tradebook, Island,
RediBook, Attain, TrackECN, BATS Trading and Direct Edge. Today, BATS
and Direct Edge provide certain market data at no charge on their Web
sites in order to attract more order flow, and use revenue rebates from
resulting additional executions to maintain low execution charges for
their users.\36\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\36\ This is simply a securities market-specific example of the
well-established principle that in certain circumstances more sales
at lower margins can be more profitable than fewer sales at higher
margins; this example is additional evidence that market data is an
inherent part of a market's joint platform.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Further, data products are valuable to certain end users only
insofar as they provide information that end users expect will assist
them or their customers. The Exchange believes the proposed non-display
fees will benefit customers by providing them with a clearer way to
determine their fee liability for non-display devices, and with respect
to internal use, to obviate the need to count such devices. The
Exchange further believes that only vendors that expect to derive a
reasonable benefit from redistributing the market data products
described herein will choose to become Redistributors and pay the
attendant monthly fees.
In establishing the proposed fees, the Exchange considered the
competitiveness of the market for proprietary data and all of the
implications of that competition. The Exchange believes that it has
considered all relevant factors and has not considered irrelevant
factors in order to establish fair, reasonable, and not unreasonably
discriminatory fees and an equitable allocation of fees among all
users. The existence of numerous alternatives to the Exchange's
products, including proprietary data from other sources, ensures that
the Exchange cannot set unreasonable fees, or fees that are
unreasonably discriminatory, when vendors and subscribers can elect
these alternatives or choose not to purchase a specific proprietary
data product if its cost to purchase is not justified by the returns
any particular vendor or subscriber would achieve through the purchase.
C. Self-Regulatory Organization's Statement on Comments on the Proposed
Rule Change Received From Members, Participants, or Others
The Exchange published draft Data Policies on its Web site on
November 20, 2012. Among other things, the Data Policies addressed non-
display use for certain market data products. The Exchange solicited
comments on the Data Policies in the form of a survey. The Exchange
received 14 comments relating to non-display use. Exhibit 2 contains a
copy of the notice soliciting comment, the Data Policies, the 14
comments received in alphabetical order, and an alphabetical listing of
such comments.
Nine commenters \37\ requested greater clarity with respect to the
definition and examples of non-display use. Specifically, the
commenters requested that the Exchange provide a consistent definition
of non-display use. As described above, the definition of non-display
use will be accessing, processing or consuming an NYSE data product
delivered via direct and/or Redistributor data feeds, for a purpose
other than in support of its display or further internal or external
redistribution. The Exchange believes that this definition addresses
the comments and will clearly describe the types of activities that
will qualify for the proposed fee. The Exchange also provided examples
for illustrative purposes, which are not exclusive.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\37\ Barclays, Brown Brothers Harriman, CMC Markets, Deutsche
Bank, Flowtraders, Nomura, Threadneedle, Transtrend BV, and UBS.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Four commenters \38\ also questioned whether price referencing,
compliance, accounting or auditing activities, and derived data should
be considered non-display use. The Data Policies listed price
referencing, compliance, accounting or auditing activities, and derived
data as examples of non-display usage; however, as discussed above, the
Exchange has determined that price referencing for the purposes of
algorithmic trading and/or smart order routing would be considered Non-
Display Trading Activities, and applications that use the data product
for non-trading activities, such as compliance, accounting or auditing
activities, and derived data are not covered by the non-display fees
and are subject to the current standard per-device fee structure.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\38\ Barclays, CMC Markets, Transtrend BV, and UBS.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Three commenters \39\ requested clarity on the NYSE Unit-of-Count
Policy for non-display use. As discussed above, the NYSE Unit-of-Count
Policy will continue to apply to Redistributors and customers that have
been approved under the NYSE Unit-of Count Policy. Under the proposed
rule change, the pricing structure for display usage will remain the
same. However, for non-display usage, customers approved under the NYSE
Unit-of-Count Policy will be eligible for the managed non-display
services at the managed non-display fee, which is offered either
directly from the Exchange or through a Redistributor.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\39\ Barclays, Essex Radez LLC, and UBS.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Two commenters \40\ asked for more detail on the managed non-
display service, which the Exchange has provided above.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\40\ FXCM and RTS Group.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Three commenters \41\ asked for examples of how the Exchange would
charge for customers that use both display and non-display devices. The
Exchange believes that the pricing examples provided above are
responsive to this request. One commenter \42\ stated that the proposed
fees are excessive. The Exchange believes that the proposed fees are
reasonable, equitable,
[[Page 20981]]
and not unfairly discriminatory for the reasons discussed in Section
3(b) above.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\41\ Essex Radez LLC, Fidelity Market Data, and Lloyds TSB Bank
plc.
\42\ Essex Radez LLC.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
III. Date of Effectiveness of the Proposed Rule Change and Timing for
Commission Action
The foregoing rule change is effective upon filing pursuant to
Section 19(b)(3)(A) \43\ of the Act and subparagraph (f)(2) of Rule
19b-4 \44\ thereunder, because it establishes a due, fee, or other
charge imposed by the Exchange.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\43\ 15 U.S.C. 78s(b)(3)(A).
\44\ 17 CFR 240.19b-4(f)(2).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
At any time within 60 days of the filing of such proposed rule
change, the Commission summarily may temporarily suspend such rule
change if it appears to the Commission that such action is necessary or
appropriate in the public interest, for the protection of investors, or
otherwise in furtherance of the purposes of the Act. If the Commission
takes such action, the Commission shall institute proceedings under
Section 19(b)(2)(B) \45\ of the Act to determine whether the proposed
rule change should be approved or disapproved.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\45\ 15 U.S.C. 78s(b)(2)(B).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
IV. Solicitation of Comments
Interested persons are invited to submit written data, views, and
arguments concerning the foregoing, including whether the proposed rule
change is consistent with the Act. Comments may be submitted by any of
the following methods:
Electronic Comments
Use the Commission's Internet comment form (https://www.sec.gov/rules/sro.shtml); or
Send an email to rule-comments@sec.gov. Please include
File Number SR-NYSE-2013-25 on the subject line.
Paper Comments
Send paper comments in triplicate to Elizabeth M. Murphy,
Secretary, Securities and Exchange Commission, 100 F Street NE.,
Washington, DC 20549-1090.
All submissions should refer to File Number SR-NYSE-2013-25. This file
number should be included on the subject line if email is used. To help
the Commission process and review your comments more efficiently,
please use only one method. The Commission will post all comments on
the Commission's Internet Web site (https://www.sec.gov/rules/sro.shtml). Copies of the submission, all subsequent amendments, all
written statements with respect to the proposed rule change that are
filed with the Commission, and all written communications relating to
the proposed rule change between the Commission and any person, other
than those that may be withheld from the public in accordance with the
provisions of 5 U.S.C. 552, will be available for Web site viewing and
printing in the Commission's Public Reference Room, 100 F Street NE.,
Washington, DC 20549, on official business days between the hours of
10:00 a.m. and 3:00 p.m. Copies of the filing also will be available
for inspection and copying at the principal office of the Exchange. All
comments received will be posted without change; the Commission does
not edit personal identifying information from submissions. You should
submit only information that you wish to make available publicly. All
submissions should refer to File Number SR-NYSE-2013-25 and should be
submitted on or before April 29, 2013.
For the Commission, by the Division of Trading and Markets,
pursuant to delegated authority.\46\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\46\ 17 CFR 200.30-3(a)(12).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Kevin M. O'Neill,
Deputy Secretary.
[FR Doc. 2013-08098 Filed 4-5-13; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 8011-01-P