President's Working Group Report on Money Market Fund Reform, 68636-68654 [2010-28177]
Download as PDF
68636
Federal Register / Vol. 75, No. 215 / Monday, November 8, 2010 / Notices
by § 17(d) of the Act, and Rule 17d–2
thereunder.
24. Counterparts. This Agreement
may be executed in any number of
counterparts, including facsimile, each
of which will be deemed an original, but
all of which taken together shall
constitute one single agreement among
the Participating Organizations.
*
*
*
*
*
EXHIBIT A
COVERED REGULATION NMS RULES
SEA Rule 611(a)—Order Protection
Rule.—Reasonable Policies and
Procedures.
SEA Rule 611(b)—Order Protection
Rule.—Exceptions.
SEA Rule 612—Minimum Pricing
Increment.
III. Date of Effectiveness of the
Proposed Plan and Timing for
Commission Action
Pursuant to Section 17(d)(1) of the
Act 14 and Rule 17d–2 thereunder,15
after November 29, 2010, the
Commission may, by written notice,
declare the proposed Plan, File No. 4–
618, to be effective if the Commission
finds that the plan is necessary or
appropriate in the public interest and
for the protection of investors, to foster
cooperation and coordination among
self-regulatory organizations, or to
remove impediments to and foster the
development of the national market
system and a national system for the
clearance and settlement of securities
transactions and in conformity with the
factors set forth in Section 17(d) of the
Act.
jlentini on DSKJ8SOYB1PROD with NOTICES
IV. Solicitation of Comments
In order to assist the Commission in
determining whether to approve the
proposed 17d–2 Plan and to relieve the
Participating Organizations of the
responsibilities which would be
assigned to FINRA, interested persons
are invited to submit written data,
views, and arguments concerning the
foregoing. Comments may be submitted
by any of the following methods:
Electronic Comments
• Use the Commission’s Internet
comment form (https://www.sec.gov/
rules/other.shtml); or
• Send an e-mail to rulecomments@sec.gov. Please include File
Number 4–618 on the subject line.
Paper Comments
• Send paper comments in triplicate
to Elizabeth M. Murphy, Secretary,
14 15
15 17
U.S.C. 78q(d)(1).
CFR 240.17d–2.
VerDate Mar<15>2010
18:02 Nov 05, 2010
Securities and Exchange Commission,
Station Place, 100 F Street, NE.,
Washington, DC 20549–1090.
All submissions should refer to File
Number 4–618. This file number should
be included on the subject line if e-mail
is used. To help the Commission
process and review your comments
more efficiently, please use only one
method. The Commission will post all
comments on the Commission’s Internet
Web site (https://www.sec.gov/rules/
other.shtml). Copies of the submission,
all subsequent amendments, all written
statements with respect to the proposed
plan that are filed with the Commission,
and all written communications relating
to the proposed plan between the
Commission and any person, other than
those that may be withheld from the
public in accordance with the
provisions of 5 U.S.C. 552, will be
available for Web site viewing and
printing in the Commission’s Public
Reference Room, on official business
days between the hours of 10 a.m. and
3 p.m. Copies of the plan also will be
available for inspection and copying at
the principal offices of the Participating
Organizations. All comments received
will be posted without change; the
Commission does not edit personal
identifying information from
submissions. You should submit only
information that you wish to make
available publicly. All submissions
should refer to File Number 4–618 and
should be submitted on or before
November 29, 2010.
For the Commission, by the Division of
Trading and Markets, pursuant to delegated
authority.16
Florence E. Harmon,
Deputy Secretary.
[FR Doc. 2010–28185 Filed 11–5–10; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 8011–01–P
SECURITIES AND EXCHANGE
COMMISSION
[File No. 500–1]
8000, Inc.; Order of Suspension of
Trading
November 4, 2010.
It appears to the Securities and
Exchange Commission that there is a
lack of current and accurate information
concerning the securities of 8000, Inc.
because of questions regarding the
accuracy of statements made by 8000,
Inc. in press releases concerning, among
other things, a cash dividend the
company announced it would pay
stockholders and Monk’s Den, an
16 17
Jkt 223001
PO 00000
CFR 200.30–3(a)(34).
Frm 00041
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
investment program and online investor
network the company disclosed it
acquired in September 2010.
The Commission is of the opinion that
the public interest and the protection of
investors require a suspension of trading
in the securities of 8000, Inc.
Therefore, it is ordered, pursuant to
Section 12(k) of the Securities Exchange
Act of 1934, that trading in the
securities of the above-listed company is
suspended for the period from 9:30 a.m.
EDT on November 4, 2010, through
11:59 p.m. EST on November 17, 2010.
By the Commission.
Jill M. Peterson,
Assistant Secretary.
[FR Doc. 2010–28241 Filed 11–4–10; 4:15 pm]
BILLING CODE 8011–01–P
SECURITIES AND EXCHANGE
COMMISSION
[Release No. IC–29497; File No. 4–619]
President’s Working Group Report on
Money Market Fund Reform
Securities and Exchange
Commission.
ACTION: Request for comment.
AGENCY:
The Securities and Exchange
Commission (‘‘Commission’’ or ‘‘SEC’’) is
seeking comment on the options
discussed in the report presenting the
results of the President’s Working Group
on Financial Markets’ study of possible
money market fund reforms. Public
comments on the options discussed in
this report will help inform
consideration of reform proposals
addressing money market funds’
susceptibility to runs.
DATES: Comments should be received on
or before January 10, 2011.
ADDRESSES: Comments may be
submitted by any of the following
methods:
SUMMARY:
Electronic Comments
• Use the Commission’s Internet
comment form (https://www.sec.gov/
rules/other.shtml); or
• Send an e-mail to rulecomments@sec.gov. Please include File
Number 4–619 on the subject line; or
• Use the Federal eRulemaking Portal
(https://www.regulations.gov). Follow the
instructions for submitting comments.
Paper Comments
• Send paper comments in triplicate
to Elizabeth M. Murphy, Secretary,
Securities and Exchange Commission,
100 F Street, NE., Washington, DC
20549–1090.
All submissions should refer to File
Number 4–619. This file number should
E:\FR\FM\08NON1.SGM
08NON1
Federal Register / Vol. 75, No. 215 / Monday, November 8, 2010 / Notices
be included on the subject line if e-mail
is used. To help us process and review
your comments more efficiently, please
use only one method. The Commission
will post all comments on the
Commission’s Internet Web site (https://
www.sec.gov/rules/other.shtml).
Comments are also available for Web
site viewing and printing in the
Commission’s Public Reference Room,
100 F Street, NE., Washington, DC
20549, on official business days
between the hours of 10 am and 3 pm.
All comments received will be posted
without change; we do not edit personal
identifying information from
submissions. You should submit only
information that you wish to make
available publicly.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
Daniele Marchesani or Sarah ten
Siethoff at (202) 551–6792, Division of
Investment Management, Securities and
Exchange Commission, 100 F Street,
NE., Washington, DC 20549–8549.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION:
I. The President’s Working Group
Report
Following the recommendation in the
U.S. Department of the Treasury’s 2009
paper on Financial Regulatory Reform:
A New Foundation, the President’s
Working Group on Financial Markets
(‘‘PWG’’) conducted a study of possible
reforms that might mitigate money
market funds’ susceptibility to runs.1
The results of this study are included in
the report issued on October 21, 2010
and attached to this release as an
Appendix (the ‘‘Report’’).2
The Report expresses support for the
new rules regulating money market
funds that the Commission approved
last February.3 These new rules seek to
jlentini on DSKJ8SOYB1PROD with NOTICES
1 The members of the PWG include the Secretary
of the Treasury Department (as chairman of the
PWG), the Chairman of the Board of Governors of
the Federal Reserve System, the Chairman of the
SEC, and the Chairman of the Commodity Futures
Trading Commission.
2 The Report is also available at https://treas.gov/
press/releases/docs/
10.21%20PWG%20Report%20Final.pdf.
3 Money Market Fund Reform, Investment
Company Act Release No. 29132 (Feb. 23, 2010) [75
FR 10060 (Mar. 4, 2010)] (‘‘SEC Adopting Release’’).
VerDate Mar<15>2010
18:02 Nov 05, 2010
Jkt 223001
better protect money market fund
investors in times of financial market
turmoil and lessen the possibility that
money market funds will not be able to
withstand stresses similar to those
experienced in 2007 and 2008.4 When
we adopted these rules, we recognized
that they were a first step to addressing
regulatory concerns as the events of
2007 and 2008 raised the question of
whether further, more fundamental
changes to the regulatory structure
governing money market funds may be
warranted.5
The Report identifies the features that
make money market funds susceptible
to runs as well as the systemic
implications of the run on prime money
market funds that occurred in
September 2008. The Report states that
the Commission’s new rules alone could
not be expected to prevent a run of the
type experienced in September 2008.
Accordingly, the Report outlines
possible reforms that could supplement
the new rules we adopted and,
individually or in combination, further
reduce money market funds’
susceptibility to runs and the related
systemic risk. Some of the measures
discussed in the Report could be
implemented by the Commission under
our existing statutory authority; others
would require new legislation,
4 The new rules further limit the credit, liquidity,
and interest rate risks money market funds may
assume and require fund managers to stress test
their portfolios against potential economic shocks.
They also require money market funds to improve
their disclosure to investors and the Commission
and provide a means to wind down the operations
of a fund that ‘‘breaks the buck’’ or suffers a run,
in an orderly way that is fair to the fund’s investors
and reduces the risk of market losses that could
spread to other funds. For a discussion of the
market stresses experienced by money market funds
in 2007 and 2008, see Money Market Fund Reform,
Investment Company Act Release No. 28807 (June
30, 2009) [74 FR 32688 (July 8, 2009)], at section
II.D (‘‘SEC Proposing Release’’).
5 See SEC Adopting Release, supra note 3, at
section I. In proposing the new rules, we had
requested comment on additional, more
fundamental regulatory changes, including several
of those discussed in the Report. See SEC Proposing
Release, supra note 4, at section III. Following the
adoption of the new rules, the Commission has
continued to explore more significant changes in
light of the comments received on that release and
through our staff’s work within the PWG.
PO 00000
Frm 00042
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
68637
coordination by multiple government
agencies, or the creation of new private
entities.6
II. Request for Comment
The Commission requests comment
on the Report. Comments received will
better enable the Commission and the
newly-established Financial Stability
Oversight Council (which will be taking
over the work of the PWG in this area)
to consider the options discussed in this
Report to identify those most likely to
materially reduce money market funds’
susceptibility to runs and to pursue
their implementation. As the Report
states, we anticipate that following the
comment period a series of meetings
will be held in Washington, DC with
various stakeholders, interested persons,
experts, and regulators to discuss the
options in the Report.
We request comments on the options
described in the Report both
individually and in combination.
Commenters should address the
effectiveness of the options in mitigating
systemic risks associated with money
market funds, as well as their potential
impact on money market fund investors,
fund managers, issuers of short-term
debt and other stakeholders. We also are
interested in comments on other issues
commenters believe are relevant to
further money market fund reform,
including other approaches for
lessening systemic risk not identified in
the Report. We urge commenters to
submit empirical data and other
information in support of their
comments.
Dated: November 3, 2010.
By the Commission.
Elizabeth M. Murphy,
Secretary.
BILLING CODE 8011–01–P
6 In particular, the Report notes that reforms may
be needed to avoid migration of institutional money
market fund assets into unregulated or less
regulated money market investment vehicles.
Without new restrictions on such investment
vehicles, money market reform may motivate some
investors to shift assets into money market fund
substitutes that may pose greater systemic risk than
registered money market funds. See section 3.h of
the Report.
E:\FR\FM\08NON1.SGM
08NON1
Federal Register / Vol. 75, No. 215 / Monday, November 8, 2010 / Notices
BILLING CODE 8011–01–C
VerDate Mar<15>2010
18:02 Nov 05, 2010
Jkt 223001
PO 00000
Frm 00043
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
E:\FR\FM\08NON1.SGM
08NON1
EN08NO10.038
jlentini on DSKJ8SOYB1PROD with NOTICES
68638
Federal Register / Vol. 75, No. 215 / Monday, November 8, 2010 / Notices
jlentini on DSKJ8SOYB1PROD with NOTICES
Table of Contents
Executive Summary
1. Introduction and Background
a. Money Market Funds
b. MMFs’ Susceptibility to Runs
c. MMFs in the Recent Financial Crisis
2. The SEC’s Changes to the Regulation of
MMFs
a. SEC Regulatory Changes
b. Need for Further Reform To Reduce
Susceptibility to Runs
3. Policy Options for Further Reducing the
Risks of Runs on MMFs
a. Floating Net Asset Values
b. Private Emergency Liquidity Facility for
MMFs
c. Mandatory Redemptions in Kind
d. Insurance for MMFs
e. A Two-Tier System of MMFs, With
Enhanced Protections for Stable NAV
MMFs
f. A Two-Tier System of MMFs, With
Stable NAV MMFs Reserved for Retail
Investors
g. Regulating Stable NAV MMFs as Special
Purpose Banks
h. Enhanced Constraints on Unregulated
MMF Substitutes
Executive Summary
Several key events during the
financial crisis underscored the
vulnerability of the financial system to
systemic risk. One such event was the
September 2008 run on money market
funds (MMFs), which began after the
failure of Lehman Brothers Holdings,
Inc., caused significant capital losses at
a large MMF. Amid broad concerns
about the safety of MMFs and other
financial institutions, investors rapidly
redeemed MMF shares, and the cash
needs of MMFs exacerbated strains in
short-term funding markets. These
strains, in turn, threatened the broader
economy, as firms and institutions
dependent upon those markets for shortterm financing found credit increasingly
difficult to obtain. Forceful government
action was taken to stop the run, restore
investor confidence, and prevent the
development of an even more severe
recession. Even so, short-term funding
markets remained disrupted for some
time.
The Treasury Department proposed in
its Financial Regulatory Reform: A New
Foundation (2009), that the President’s
Working Group on Financial Markets
(PWG) prepare a report on fundamental
changes needed to address systemic risk
and to reduce the susceptibility of
MMFs to runs. Treasury stated that the
Securities and Exchange Commission’s
(SEC) rule amendments to strengthen
the regulation of MMFs—which were in
development at the time and which
subsequently have been adopted—
should enhance investor protection and
mitigate the risk of runs. However,
Treasury also noted that those rule
VerDate Mar<15>2010
18:02 Nov 05, 2010
Jkt 223001
changes could not, by themselves, be
expected to prevent a run on MMFs of
the scale experienced in September
2008. While suggesting a number of
areas for review, Treasury added that
the PWG should consider ways to
mitigate possible adverse effects of
further regulatory changes, such as the
potential flight of assets from MMFs to
less regulated or unregulated vehicles.
This report by the PWG responds to
Treasury’s call.7 The PWG undertook a
study of possible further reforms that,
individually or in combination, might
mitigate systemic risk by
complementing the SEC’s changes to
MMF regulation. The PWG supports the
SEC’s recent actions and agrees with the
SEC that more should be done to
address MMFs’ susceptibility to runs.
This report details a number of options
for further reform that the PWG requests
be examined by the newly established
Financial Stability Oversight Council
(FSOC). These options range from
measures that could be implemented by
the SEC under current statutory
authorities to broader changes that
would require new legislation,
coordination by multiple government
agencies, and the creation of new
private entities. For example, a new
requirement that MMFs adopt floating
net asset values (NAVs) or that large
funds meet redemption requests in kind
could be accomplished by SEC rule
amendments. In contrast, the
introduction of a private emergency
liquidity facility, insurance for MMFs,
conversion of MMFs to special purpose
banks, or a two-tier system of MMFs
that might combine some of the other
measures likely would involve a
coordinated effort by the SEC, bank
regulators, and financial firms.
Importantly, this report also
emphasizes that the efficacy of the
options presented herein would be
enhanced considerably by the
imposition of new constraints on less
regulated or unregulated MMF
substitutes, such as offshore MMFs,
enhanced cash funds, and other stable
value vehicles. Without new restrictions
on such investment vehicles, which
would require legislation, new rules that
further constrain MMFs may motivate
some investors to shift assets into MMF
substitutes that may pose greater
systemic risk than MMFs.
The PWG requests that the FSOC
consider the options discussed in this
7 The PWG (established by Executive Order
12631) is comprised of the Secretary of the Treasury
(who serves as its Chairman), the Chairman of the
Federal Reserve Board of Governors, the Chairman
of the Securities and Exchange Commission, and
the Chairman of the Commodity Futures Trading
Commission.
PO 00000
Frm 00044
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
68639
report to identify those most likely to
materially reduce MMFs’ susceptibility
to runs and to pursue their
implementation. To assist the FSOC in
any analysis, the SEC, as the regulator
of MMFs, will solicit public comments,
including the production of empirical
data and other information in support of
such comments. A notice and request
for comment will be published in the
near future. Following a comment
period, a series of meetings will be held
in Washington, DC with various
stakeholders, interested persons,
experts, and regulators.
MMFs Are Susceptible to Runs
MMFs are mutual funds. They are
investment vehicles that act as
intermediaries between shareholders
who desire liquid investments and
borrowers who seek term funding. With
nearly $3 trillion in assets under
management, MMFs are important
providers of credit to businesses,
financial institutions, and governments.
In addition, these funds are significant
investors in some short-term funding
markets.
Like other mutual funds, MMFs are
regulated under the Investment
Company Act of 1940 (ICA). In addition
to ICA requirements for all mutual
funds, MMFs must comply with SEC
rule 2a–7, which permits these funds to
maintain a stable net asset value (NAV)
per share, typically $1. However, if the
mark-to-market per-share value of a
fund’s assets falls more than one-half of
1 percent (to below $0.995), the fund
must reprice its shares, an event
colloquially known as ‘‘breaking the
buck.’’
The events of September 2008
demonstrated that MMFs are susceptible
to runs. In addition, those events proved
that runs on MMFs not only harm fund
shareholders, but may also cause severe
dislocations in short-term funding
markets that curtail short-term financing
for companies and financial institutions
and that ultimately result in a decline in
economic activity. Thus, reducing the
susceptibility of MMFs to runs and
mitigating the effects of possible runs
are important components of the overall
policy goals of decreasing and
containing systemic risks.
MMFs are vulnerable to runs because
shareholders have an incentive to
redeem their shares before others do
when there is a perception that the fund
might suffer a loss. Several features of
MMFs, their sponsors, and their
investors contribute to this incentive.
For example, although a stable, rounded
$1 NAV fosters an expectation of safety,
MMFs are subject to credit, interest-rate,
and liquidity risks. Thus, when a fund
E:\FR\FM\08NON1.SGM
08NON1
68640
Federal Register / Vol. 75, No. 215 / Monday, November 8, 2010 / Notices
incurs even a small loss because of
those risks, the stable, rounded NAV
may subsidize shareholders who choose
to redeem at the expense of the
remaining shareholders. A larger loss
that causes a fund’s share price to drop
below $1 per share (and thus break the
buck) may prompt more substantial
sudden, destabilizing redemptions.
Moreover, although the expectations of
safety fostered by the stable, rounded $1
NAV suggest parallels to an insured
demand deposit account, MMFs have no
formal capital buffers or insurance to
prevent NAV declines; MMFs instead
have relied historically on discretionary
sponsor capital support to maintain
stable NAVs. Accordingly, uncertainty
about the availability of such support
during crises may contribute to runs.
Finally, because investors have come to
view MMFs as extremely safe vehicles
that meet all withdrawal requests on
demand (and that are, in this sense,
similar to banks), MMFs have attracted
highly risk-averse investors who are
particularly prone to flight when they
perceive the possibility of a loss. These
features likely mutually reinforce each
other in times of crisis.
jlentini on DSKJ8SOYB1PROD with NOTICES
The SEC’s New Rules
In January 2010, the SEC adopted new
rules for MMFs in order to make these
funds more resilient and less likely to
break the buck. The regulatory changes
that mitigate systemic risks fall into
three principal categories. First, the new
rules enhance risk-limiting constraints
on MMF portfolios by introducing new
liquidity requirements, imposing
additional credit-quality standards, and
reducing the maximum allowable
weighted average maturity of funds’
portfolios. Funds also are required to
stress test their ability to maintain a
stable NAV. Second, the SEC’s new
rules permit a fund that is breaking the
buck to suspend redemptions promptly
and liquidate its portfolio in an orderly
manner to limit contagion effects on
other funds. Third, the new rules place
more stringent constraints on
repurchase agreements that are
collateralized with private debt
instruments rather than government
securities.
The Need for Further Measures
The SEC’s new rules make MMFs
more resilient and less risky and
therefore reduce the likelihood of runs
on MMFs, increase the size of runs that
MMFs can withstand, and mitigate the
systemic risks they pose. However, the
SEC’s new rules address only some of
the features that make MMFs
susceptible to runs, and more should be
done to address systemic risk and the
VerDate Mar<15>2010
18:02 Nov 05, 2010
Jkt 223001
structural vulnerabilities of MMFs to
runs. Indeed, the Chairman of the SEC
characterized the new rules as ‘‘a first
step’’ in strengthening MMFs, and
Treasury’s Financial Regulatory Reform:
A New Foundation (2009) anticipated
that measures taken by the SEC ‘‘should
not, by themselves, be expected to
prevent a run on MMFs of the scale
experienced in September 2008.’’
Mitigating the risk of runs on MMFs
is especially important because the
events of September 2008 may have
created an expectation that, in a future
crisis, the government may provide
support for MMFs at minimal cost in
order to minimize harm to MMF
investors, short-term funding markets,
and the economy. Persistent
expectations of unpriced government
support distort incentives in the MMF
industry and pricing in short-term
funding markets, as well as heighten the
systemic risk posed by MMFs. It is thus
essential that MMFs be required to
internalize fully the costs of liquidity or
other risks associated with their
operation.
In formulating reforms for MMFs,
policymakers should aim primarily at
mitigating systemic risk and containing
the contagious effect that strains at
individual MMFs can have on other
MMFs and on the broad financial
system. Importantly, preventing any
individual MMF from ever breaking the
buck is not a practical policy objective—
though the new SEC rules for MMFs
should help ensure that such events
remain rare and thus constitute a
limited means of containing systemic
risk.
Policy Options
The policy options discussed in this
report may help further mitigate the
susceptibility of MMFs to runs. Some of
these options may be adopted by the
SEC under its existing authorities.
Others would require legislation and
action by multiple government agencies
and the MMF industry.
(a) Floating net asset values. A stable
NAV has been a key element of the
appeal of MMFs to investors, but a
stable, rounded NAV also heightens
funds’ vulnerability to runs. Moving to
a floating NAV would help remove the
perception that MMFs are risk-free and
reduce investors’ incentives to redeem
shares from distressed funds. However,
the elimination of the stable NAV for
MMFs would be a dramatic change for
a nearly $3 trillion asset-management
sector that has been built around the
stable share price. Such a change may
have several unintended consequences,
including: (i) Reductions in MMFs’
capacity to provide short-term credit
PO 00000
Frm 00045
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
due to lower investor demand; (ii) a
shift of assets to less regulated or
unregulated MMF substitutes such as
offshore MMFs, enhanced cash funds,
and other stable value vehicles; and
(iii) unpredictable investor responses as
MMF NAVs begin to fluctuate more
frequently.
(b) Private emergency liquidity
facilities for MMFs. The liquidity risk of
MMFs contributes importantly to their
vulnerability to runs, and an external
liquidity backstop to augment the SEC’s
new liquidity requirements for MMFs
would help mitigate this risk. Such a
backstop could buttress MMFs’ ability
to withstand outflows, internalize much
of the liquidity protection costs for the
MMF industry, offer efficiency gains
from risk pooling, and reduce contagion
effects. A liquidity facility would
preserve fund advisers’ incentives for
not taking excessive risks because it
would not protect funds from capital
losses. As such, a liquidity facility alone
may not prevent broader runs on MMFs
triggered by concerns about widespread
credit losses. Importantly, significant
capacity, structure, pricing, and
operational hurdles would have to be
overcome to ensure that such a facility
would be effective during crises, that it
would not unduly distort incentives,
and that it would not favor certain types
of MMF business models.
(c) Mandatory redemptions in kind.
When investors make large redemptions
from MMFs, they may impose liquidity
costs on other shareholders in the fund
by forcing MMFs to sell assets in an
untimely manner. A requirement that
MMFs distribute large redemptions in
kind, rather than in cash, would force
these redeeming shareholders to bear
their own liquidity costs and thus
reduce the incentive to redeem.
Depending on whether redeeming
shareholders immediately sell the
securities received, redemptions in kind
may still generate market effects.
Moreover, mandating redemptions in
kind could present some operational
and policy challenges. The SEC, for
example, would have to make key
judgments regarding when a fund must
redeem in kind and how funds would
fairly distribute portfolio securities.
(d) Insurance for MMFs. Treasury’s
Temporary Guarantee Program for
Money Market Funds helped slow the
run on MMFs in September 2008, and
some form of insurance for MMF
shareholders might be helpful in
mitigating the risk of runs in MMFs.
Unlike a private liquidity facility,
insurance would limit credit losses to
shareholders, so appropriate risk-based
pricing would be critical in preventing
insurance from distorting incentives,
E:\FR\FM\08NON1.SGM
08NON1
jlentini on DSKJ8SOYB1PROD with NOTICES
Federal Register / Vol. 75, No. 215 / Monday, November 8, 2010 / Notices
but such pricing might be difficult to
achieve in practice. The appropriate
scope of coverage also presents a
challenge; unlimited coverage would
likely cause large shifts of assets from
the banking sector to MMFs, but limited
insurance might do little to reduce
institutional investors’ incentives to run
from distressed MMFs. The optimal
form for insurance—whether it would
be private, public, or a mix of the two—
is also uncertain, particularly given the
recent experience with private financial
guarantees.
(e) A two-tier system of MMFs with
enhanced protection for stable NAV
funds. Reforms aimed at reducing
MMFs’ susceptibility to runs may be
particularly effective if they permit
investors to select the types of MMFs
that best balance their appetite for risk
and their preference for yield.
Policymakers could allow two types of
MMFs: Stable NAV funds, which would
be subject to enhanced protections such
as, for example, required participation
in a private liquidity facility or
enhanced regulatory requirements; and
floating NAV funds, which would have
to comply with certain, but not all, rule
2a–7 restrictions (and which would
presumably offer higher yields). Because
this two-tier system would permit stable
NAV funds to continue to be available,
it would reduce the likelihood of a
substantial decline in demand for MMFs
and large-scale shifts of assets toward
unregulated vehicles. At the same time,
the forms of protection encompassed by
such a system would mitigate the risks
associated with stable NAV funds. It
would also avoid problems that might
be encountered in transitioning the
entire MMF industry to a floating NAV.
Moreover, during a crisis, a two-tier
system might prevent large shifts of
assets out of MMFs—and a reduction in
credit supplied by the funds—if
investors simply shift assets from riskier
floating NAV funds toward safer
(because of the enhanced protections)
stable NAV funds. However,
implementation of such a two-tier
system would present the same
challenges as the introduction of any
individual enhanced protections (such
as mandated access to a private
emergency liquidity facility) that would
be required for stable NAV funds, and
the effectiveness of a two-tier system
would depend on investors’
understanding the risks associated with
each type of fund.
(f) A two-tier system of MMFs with
stable NAV MMFs reserved for retail
investors. Another approach to the twotier system already described could
distinguish funds by investor type:
Stable NAV MMFs could be made
VerDate Mar<15>2010
18:02 Nov 05, 2010
Jkt 223001
available only to retail investors, who
could choose between stable NAV and
floating NAV funds, while institutional
investors would be restricted to floating
NAV funds. The run on MMFs in
September 2008 was almost exclusively
due to redemptions from prime MMFs
by institutional investors. Such
investors typically have generated
greater cash-flow volatility for MMFs
than retail investors and have been
much quicker to redeem MMF shares
from stable NAV funds
opportunistically. Hence, this approach
would mitigate risks associated with a
stable NAV by addressing the investor
base of stable NAV funds rather than by
mandating other types of enhanced
protections for those funds. Such a
system also would protect the interests
of retail investors by reducing the
likelihood that a run might begin in
institutional MMFs (as it did in
September 2008) and spread to retail
funds, while preserving the original
purpose of MMFs, which was to provide
retail investors with cost-effective,
diversified investments in money
market instruments. This approach
would require the SEC to define who
would qualify as retail and institutional
investors, and distinguishing those
categories will present challenges. In
addition, a prohibition on sales of stable
NAV MMFs shares to institutional
investors may have several of the same
unintended consequences as a
requirement that all MMFs adopt
floating NAVs (see option (a) in this
section).
(g) Regulating stable NAV MMFs as
special purpose banks. Functional
similarities between MMF shares and
bank deposits, as well as the risk of runs
on both, provide a rationale for
requiring stable NAV MMFs to
reorganize as special purpose banks
(SPBs) subject to banking oversight and
regulation. As banks, MMFs could have
access to government insurance and
lender-of-last-resort facilities. An
advantage of such a reorganization
could be that it uses a well-understood
regulatory framework for the mitigation
of systemic risk. But while the
conceptual basis for this option is fairly
straightforward, its implementation
might take a broad range of forms and
would probably require legislation
together with interagency coordination.
An important hurdle for successful
conversion of MMFs to SPBs may be the
very large amounts of equity necessary
to capitalize the new banks. In addition,
to the extent that deposits in the new
SPBs would be insured, the potential
government liabilities through deposit
insurance would be increased
PO 00000
Frm 00046
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
68641
substantially, and the development of
an appropriate pricing scheme for such
insurance would present some of the
same challenges as the pricing of
deposit insurance. More broadly, the
possible interactions between the new
SPBs and the existing banking system
would have to be studied carefully by
policymakers.
(h) Enhanced constraints on
unregulated MMF substitutes. New
measures intended to mitigate MMF
risks may also reduce the appeal of
MMFs to many investors. While it is
likely that some (particularly retail)
investors may move their assets from
MMFs to bank deposits if regulation of
MMFs becomes too burdensome and
meaningfully reduces MMF returns,
others may be motivated to shift assets
to unregulated funds with stable NAVs,
such as offshore MMFs, enhanced cash
funds, and other stable value vehicles.
Such funds, which typically hold assets
similar to those held by MMFs, are
vulnerable to runs but are less
transparent and less constrained than
MMFs, so their growth would likely
pose systemic risks. Hence, effective
mitigation of this risk may require
policy reforms targeting regulatory
arbitrage. Reforms of this type generally
would require legislation and action by
the SEC and other agencies.
1. Introduction and Background
a. Money Market Funds
MMFs are mutual funds that offer
individuals, businesses, and
governments a convenient and costeffective means of pooled investing in
money market instruments. MMFs
provide an economically important
service by acting as intermediaries
between shareholders who desire liquid
investments, often for cash
management, and borrowers who seek
term funding.
With nearly $3 trillion in assets under
management, MMFs are important
providers of credit to businesses,
financial institutions, and governments.
Indeed, these funds play a dominant
role in some short-term credit markets.
For example, MMFs own almost 40
percent of outstanding commercial
paper, roughly two-thirds of short-term
state and local government debt, and
significant portions of outstanding
short-term Treasury and federal agency
securities.
Like other mutual funds, MMFs are
regulated under the Investment
Company Act of 1940 (ICA). In addition
to the requirements applicable to other
funds under the ICA, MMFs must
comply with rule 2a–7, which permits
these funds to maintain a ‘‘stable’’ net
E:\FR\FM\08NON1.SGM
08NON1
jlentini on DSKJ8SOYB1PROD with NOTICES
68642
Federal Register / Vol. 75, No. 215 / Monday, November 8, 2010 / Notices
asset value (NAV) per share, typically
$1, through the use of the ‘‘amortized
cost’’ method of valuation. Under this
method, securities are valued at
acquisition cost, with adjustments for
amortization of premium or accretion of
discount, instead of at fair market value.
To prevent substantial deviations
between the $1 share price and the
mark-to-market per-share value of the
fund’s assets (its ‘‘shadow NAV’’), a
MMF must periodically compare the
two. If there is a difference of more than
one-half of 1 percent (or $0.005 per
share), the fund must re-price its shares,
an event colloquially known as
‘‘breaking the buck.’’
Historically, the stable NAV has
played an important role in
distinguishing MMFs from other mutual
funds and in facilitating the use of
MMFs as cash management vehicles.
Rule 2a–7 also imposes credit-quality,
maturity, and diversification
requirements on MMF portfolios
designed to ensure that the funds’
investing remains consistent with the
objective of maintaining a stable NAV.
A MMF’s $1 share price is not
guaranteed through any form of deposit
or other insurance, or otherwise—
indeed, MMF prospectuses must state
that shares can lose value. However, by
permitting amortized cost valuation,
rule 2a–7 affords MMFs price stability
under normal market conditions.
MMFs pursue a range of investment
objectives, with corresponding
differences in portfolio composition. For
example, tax-exempt MMFs purchase
short-term municipal securities and
offer tax-exempt income to fund
shareholders, while Treasury-only
MMFs hold only obligations of the U.S.
Treasury. In contrast, prime MMFs
invest largely in private debt
instruments, such as commercial paper
and certificates of deposit, and,
commensurate with the greater risks in
prime MMF portfolios, they generally
pay higher yields than Treasury-only
funds.
MMFs are marketed both to retail
investors (that is, individuals), for
whom MMFs are the only means of
investing in many money market
instruments, and to institutions, which
are often attracted by the convenience
and cost efficiency of MMFs, even
though many institutional investors
have the ability to invest directly in the
instruments held by MMFs. Institutional
MMFs, which currently account for
about two-thirds of the assets under
management in MMFs, have grown
much faster, on net, in the past two
decades than retail funds. The rapid
growth of institutional funds has
important implications for the MMF
VerDate Mar<15>2010
18:02 Nov 05, 2010
Jkt 223001
industry, because institutional funds
tend to have more volatile flows and
more yield-sensitive shareholders than
retail funds.
MMFs compete with other stablevalue, low-risk investments. Because
MMFs generally maintain stable NAVs,
offer redemptions on demand, and often
provide services that compete with
those offered to holders of insured
deposits (such as transactions services),
many retail customers likely consider
MMF shares and bank deposits as near
substitutes, even if the two classes of
products are fundamentally different
(most notably because MMF shares are
not insured and because MMFs and
banks are subject to very different
regulatory regimes). Some institutional
investors may also view bank deposits
and MMFs as near substitutes, although
usual limitations on deposit insurance
coverage and interest payments on
deposits likely reduce the attractiveness
of bank deposits for most such
investors.8 Institutional investors also
have access to less-regulated MMF
substitutes (for example, offshore
MMFs, enhanced cash funds, and other
stable value vehicles) and may perceive
them as near substitutes for MMFs, even
if those vehicles are not subject to the
protections afforded by rule 2a–7.
b. MMFs’ Susceptibility to Runs
In the twenty-seven years since the
adoption of rule 2a–7, only two MMFs
have broken the buck. In 1994, a small
MMF suffered a capital loss because of
exposures to interest rate derivatives,
but the event passed without significant
repercussions. In contrast, as further
discussed later, when the Reserve
Primary Fund broke the buck in
September 2008, it helped ignite a
massive run on prime MMFs that
contributed to severe dislocations in
short-term credit markets and strains on
the businesses and institutions that
obtain funding in those markets.9
Although the run on MMFs in 2008 is
itself unique in the history of the
industry, the events of 2008
8 Under the Federal Deposit Insurance
Corporation’s (FDIC) Temporary Liquidity
Guarantee Program, coverage limits on noninterestbearing transaction deposits in FDIC-insured
institutions were temporarily lifted beginning in
October 2008 and coverage will extend through
2010. Effective December 31, 2010, pursuant to the
Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer
Protection Act, Public Law 111–203, (‘‘Dodd-Frank
Act’’), all noninterest-bearing transaction deposits
will have unlimited coverage until January 1, 2013.
In addition, section 627 of the Dodd-Frank Act
repeals the prohibition on banks paying interest on
corporate demand deposit accounts effective July
21, 2011.
9 Section 1(c) contains more detail on the MMF
industry’s experience during the recent financial
crisis.
PO 00000
Frm 00047
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
underscored the susceptibility of MMFs
to runs. That susceptibility arises
because, when shareholders perceive a
risk that a fund will suffer losses, each
shareholder has an incentive to redeem
shares before other shareholders. Five
features of MMFs, their sponsors, and
their investors principally contribute to
this incentive:
(i) Maturity transformation with
limited liquidity resources. One
important economic function of MMFs
is their role as intermediaries between
shareholders who want liquid
investments and borrowers who desire
term funding. As such, MMFs offer
shares that are payable on demand, but
they invest both in cash-like
instruments and in short-term securities
that are less liquid, including, for
example, term commercial paper.
Redemptions in excess of MMFs’ cashlike liquidity may force funds to sell
less liquid assets. When money markets
are strained, funds may not be able to
obtain full value (that is, amortized cost)
for such assets in secondary markets
and may incur losses as a consequence.
Investors thus have an incentive to
redeem shares before a fund has
depleted its cash-like instruments
(which serve as its liquidity buffer).
(ii) NAVs rounded to $1. Share prices
of MMFs are rounded to the nearest
cent, typically resulting in a $1 NAV per
share. The rounding fosters an
expectation that MMF share prices will
not fluctuate, which exacerbates
investors’ incentive to run when there is
risk that prices will fluctuate. When a
MMF that has experienced a small (less
than one-half of 1 percent) capital loss
redeems shares at the full $1 NAV, it
concentrates the loss among the
remaining shareholders. Thus,
redemptions from such a fund further
depress the market value of its assets
per share outstanding (its shadow NAV),
and redemptions of sufficient scale may
cause the fund to break the buck. Early
redeemers are therefore more likely to
receive the usual $1 NAV than those
who wait.
(iii) Portfolios exposed to credit and
interest rate risks. MMFs invest in
securities with credit and interest-rate
risks. Although these risks are generally
small given the short maturity of the
securities and the high degree of
portfolio diversification, even a small
capital loss, in combination with other
features of MMFs, can trigger a
significant volume of redemptions. The
events of September 2008—when losses
on Lehman Brothers Holdings, Inc.
(Lehman Brothers) debt instruments
caused just one MMF to break the buck
and triggered a broad run on MMFs—
highlight the fact that credit losses at
E:\FR\FM\08NON1.SGM
08NON1
Federal Register / Vol. 75, No. 215 / Monday, November 8, 2010 / Notices
jlentini on DSKJ8SOYB1PROD with NOTICES
even a single fund may have serious
implications for the whole industry and
consequently for the entire financial
system.10
(iv) Discretionary sponsor capital
support. MMFs invest in assets that may
lose value, but the funds have no formal
capital buffers or insurance to maintain
their $1 share prices in the event of a
loss on a portfolio asset.
The MMF industry’s record of
maintaining a stable NAV reflects, in
part, substantial discretionary
intervention by MMF sponsors (that is,
fund advisers, their affiliates, and their
parent firms) to support funds that
otherwise might have broken the
buck.11 Sponsors do not commit to
support an MMF in advance, because an
explicit commitment may require the
sponsor to consolidate the fund on its
balance sheet and—if the sponsor is
subject to regulatory capital
requirements—hold additional
regulatory capital against the contingent
exposure. Nor is there any requirement
that sponsors support ailing MMFs;
such a mandate would transform the
nature of MMF shares by shifting risks
from investors to sponsors and probably
would require government supervision
and monitoring of sponsors’ resources
and capital adequacy.12 Instead, sponsor
capital support remains expressly
voluntary, and not all MMFs have a
sponsor capable of fully supporting its
MMFs. Nonetheless, a long history of
such support probably has contributed
substantially to the perceived safety of
MMFs.
However, the possibility that sponsors
may become unwilling or unable to
provide expected support during a crisis
is itself a source of systemic risk.
Indeed, sponsor support is probably
least reliable when systemic risks are
most salient.13 Moreover, MMFs
10 Souring credits and rapid increases in interest
rates have adversely affected MMFs on other
occasions. For example, beginning in the summer
of 2007, MMF exposures to structured investment
vehicles and other asset-backed commercial paper
caused capital losses at many MMFs, and many
MMF sponsors voluntarily provided capital support
that prevented some funds from breaking the buck.
11 For example, more than 100 MMFs received
sponsor capital support in 2007 and 2008 because
of investments in securities that lost value and
because of the run on MMFs in September and
October 2008. See Securities and Exchange
Commission (2009) ‘‘Money Market Reform:
Proposed Rule,’’ pp. 13–14, 17, and notes 38 and 54.
12 Even discretionary support for MMFs may lead
to concerns about the safety and soundness of MMF
sponsors. Sponsors that foster expectations of such
support may be granting a form of implicit recourse
that is not reflected on sponsors’ balance sheets or
in their regulatory capital ratios, and such implicit
recourse may contribute to broader systemic risk.
13 Other forms of discretionary financial support,
such as that provided by dealers for auction rate
securities, did not fare well during the financial
crisis.
VerDate Mar<15>2010
18:02 Nov 05, 2010
Jkt 223001
without deep-pocketed sponsors remain
vulnerable to runs that can affect the
entire industry. The Reserve Primary
Fund was not the only MMF that held
Lehman Brothers debt at the time of the
Lehman Brothers’ bankruptcy in
September 2008, but it broke the buck
because the Reserve Primary Fund,
unlike some of its competitors, had
substantial holdings of Lehman Brothers
debt and Reserve did not have the
resources to support its fund. Investors
also recognized the riskiness of sponsor
support more broadly during the run on
MMFs in 2008. For example, outflows
from prime MMFs following the
Lehman Brothers bankruptcy tended to
be larger among MMFs with sponsors
that were themselves under strain (as
measured by credit default swap
spreads for parent firms or affiliates),
indicating that MMF investors quickly
redeemed shares on concerns about
sponsors’ potential inabilities to bolster
ailing funds.
(v) Investors’ low risk tolerance and
expectations. Investors have come to
view MMF shares as extremely safe, in
part because of the funds’ stable NAVs
and sponsors’ record of supporting
funds that might otherwise lose value.
MMFs’ history of maintaining stable
value has attracted highly risk-averse
investors who are prone to withdraw
assets rapidly when losses appear
possible.
MMFs, like other mutual funds,
commit to redeem shares based on the
fund’s NAV at the time of redemption.
MMFs are under no legal or regulatory
requirement to redeem shares at $1; rule
2a–7 only requires that MMFs be
managed to maintain a stable NAV. Yet
sponsor-supported stable, rounded
NAVs and the typical $1 MMF share
price foster investors’ impressions that
MMFs are extremely safe investments.
Indeed, the growth of retail MMFs in
recent decades may have reflected some
substitution from insured deposits at
commercial banks, thrifts, and credit
unions, particularly as MMFs have
offered transactions services and other
bank-like functions. Although MMF
shares, unlike bank deposits, are not
government insured and are not backed
by capital to absorb losses, this
distinction may have become even less
clear to retail investors following the
unprecedented government support of
MMFs in 2008 and 2009. Furthermore,
that recent support may have left even
sophisticated institutional investors
with the mistaken impression that MMF
safety is enhanced because the
government stands ready to support the
industry again with the same tools
employed at the height of the financial
crisis.
PO 00000
Frm 00048
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
68643
The growth of institutional MMFs in
recent years probably has heightened
both the risk aversion of the typical
MMF shareholder and the volatility of
MMF cash flows. Many institutional
investors cannot tolerate fluctuations in
share prices for a variety of reasons. In
addition, institutional investors are
typically more sophisticated than retail
investors in obtaining and analyzing
information about MMF portfolios and
risks, have larger amounts at stake, and
hence are quicker to respond to events
that may threaten the stable NAV. In
fact, institutional MMFs have
historically experienced much more
volatile flows than retail funds. During
the run on MMFs in September 2008,
institutional funds accounted for more
than 90 percent of the net redemptions
from prime MMFs.
The interaction of these five features
is critical. Taken alone, each of the
features just listed probably would only
modestly increase the vulnerability of
MMFs to runs, but, in combination, the
features tend to amplify and reinforce
one another. For example, equity
mutual funds perform maturity
transformation and take on capital risks,
but even after large capital losses,
outflows from equity funds tend to be
small relative to assets, most likely
because equity funds are not marketed
for their ability to maintain stable
NAVs, do not attract the risk-averse
investor base that characterizes MMFs,
and offer the opportunity for capital
appreciation. If MMFs with rounded
NAVs had lacked sponsor support over
the past few decades, many might have
broken the buck and diminished the
expectation of a stable $1 share price. In
that case, investors who nonetheless
elected to hold shares in such funds
might have become more tolerant of risk
and less inclined to run. If MMFs had
attracted primarily a retail investor base
rather than an institutional base,
investors might be slower to respond to
strains on a MMF. And even a highly
risk-averse investor base would not
necessarily make MMFs susceptible to
runs—and to contagion arising from
runs on other MMFs—if funds had a
credible means to guarantee their $1
NAVs. Thus, policy responses that
diminish the reinforcing interactions
among the features discussed herein
hold promise for muting overall risks
posed by MMFs.
c. MMFs in the Recent Financial Crisis
The turmoil in financial markets in
2007 and 2008 caused severe strains
both among MMFs and in the short-term
debt markets in which MMFs invest.
Beginning in mid-2007, dozens of funds
faced losses from holdings of highly
E:\FR\FM\08NON1.SGM
08NON1
jlentini on DSKJ8SOYB1PROD with NOTICES
68644
Federal Register / Vol. 75, No. 215 / Monday, November 8, 2010 / Notices
rated asset-backed commercial paper
(ABCP) issued by structured investment
vehicles (SIVs), some of which had
exposures to the subprime mortgage
market. Fear of such losses at one MMF
caused that fund to experience a
substantial run in August 2007, which
was brought under control when the
fund’s sponsor purchased more than
$5 billion of illiquid securities from the
fund. Indeed, financial support from
MMF sponsors in recent years probably
prevented a number of funds from
breaking the buck because of losses on
SIV paper.
The crisis for MMFs worsened
considerably in September 2008 with
the bankruptcy of Lehman Brothers on
September 15 and mounting concerns
about other issuers of commercial paper,
particularly financial firms. The Reserve
Primary Fund, a $62 billion MMF, held
$785 million in Lehman Brothers debt
on the day of Lehman Brothers’
bankruptcy and immediately began
experiencing a run—shareholders
requested redemptions of approximately
$40 billion in just two days. In order to
meet the redemptions, the Reserve
Primary Fund depleted its cash reserves
and began seeking to sell its portfolio
securities, which further depressed their
valuations. Unlike other MMFs that
held distressed securities, the Reserve
Primary Fund had no affiliate with
sufficient resources to support its $1
NAV, and Reserve announced on
September 16 that its Primary Fund
would break the buck and re-price its
shares at $0.97. On September 22, the
SEC issued an order permitting the
suspension of redemptions in certain
Reserve MMFs to permit their orderly
liquidation.
The run quickly spread to other prime
MMFs, which held sizable amounts of
financial sector debt that investors
feared might decline rapidly in value.
During the week of September 15, 2008,
investors withdrew approximately $310
billion (15 percent of assets) from prime
MMFs, with the heaviest redemptions
coming from institutional funds. To
meet these redemption requests, MMFs
depleted their cash positions and sought
to sell portfolio securities into already
illiquid markets. These efforts caused
further declines in the prices of shortterm instruments and put pressure on
per-share values of fund portfolios,
threatening MMFs’ stable NAVs.
Nonetheless, only one MMF—the
Reserve Primary Fund—broke the buck,
because many MMF sponsors provided
substantial financial support to prevent
capital losses in their funds.
Fearing further redemptions, many
MMF advisers limited new portfolio
investments to cash, U.S. Treasury
VerDate Mar<15>2010
18:02 Nov 05, 2010
Jkt 223001
securities, and overnight instruments,
and avoided term commercial paper,
certificates of deposit, and other shortterm credit instruments. During
September 2008, MMFs reduced their
holdings of commercial paper by about
$170 billion (25 percent). As market
participants hoarded cash and refused
to lend to one another on more than an
overnight basis, interest rates spiked
and short-term credit markets froze.
Commercial paper issuers were required
to make significant draws on their
backup lines of credit, placing
additional pressure on the balance
sheets of commercial banks.
On September 19, 2008, Treasury and
the Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System (Federal Reserve)
announced two unprecedented market
interventions to stabilize MMFs and to
provide liquidity to short-term funding
markets. Treasury’s Temporary
Guarantee Program for Money Market
Funds temporarily provided guarantees
for shareholders in MMFs that elected to
participate in the program.14 The
Federal Reserve’s Asset-Backed
Commercial Paper Money Market
Mutual Fund Liquidity Facility (AMLF)
extended credit to U.S. banks and bank
holding companies to finance their
purchases of high-quality ABCP from
MMFs.15
The announcements of these
government programs substantially
slowed the run on prime MMFs.
Outflows from prime MMFs diminished
to about $65 billion in the week after the
announcements and, by mid-October,
these MMFs began attracting net
inflows. Moreover, in the weeks
following the government interventions,
markets for commercial paper and other
short-term debt instruments stabilized
considerably.16
14 MMFs that elected to participate in the program
paid fees of 4 to 6 basis points at an annual rate
for the guarantee. The Temporary Guarantee
Program for Money Market Funds expired on
September 18, 2009.
15 The AMLF expired on February 1, 2010.
16 Several other unprecedented government
interventions that provided additional support for
the MMF industry and for short-term funding
markets were introduced after the run on MMFs
had largely abated. For example, the Federal
Reserve in October 2008 established the
Commercial Paper Funding Facility (CPFF), which
provided loans for purchases (through a special
purpose vehicle) of term commercial paper from
issuers. The CPFF, which expired on February 1,
2010, helped issuers repay investors—such as
MMFs—who held maturing paper. Also in October
2008, the Federal Reserve announced the Money
Market Investor Funding Facility (MMIFF), which
was intended to bolster liquidity for MMFs by
financing (through special purpose vehicles)
purchases of securities from the funds. The MMIFF
was never used and expired on October 30, 2009.
In November 2008, Treasury agreed to become a
buyer of last resort for certain securities held by the
Reserve U.S. Government Fund (a MMF), in order
PO 00000
Frm 00049
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
2. The SEC’s Changes to the Regulation
of MMFs
The effects of the financial turmoil in
2007 and 2008 on MMFs—and, in
particular, the run on these funds in
September 2008 and its consequences—
have highlighted the need for reforms to
mitigate the systemic risks posed by
MMFs. Appropriate reforms include
changes to MMF regulations as well as
broader policy actions. This section first
examines rule changes that have been
adopted by the SEC to improve the
safety and resilience of MMFs and then
discusses some limitations in these
measures’ mitigation of systemic risk
and the need for further reforms.
Notwithstanding the need for reform,
the significance of MMFs in the U.S.
financial system suggests that changes
must be considered carefully. Tighter
restrictions on MMFs might, for
example, lead to a reduction in the
supply of short-term credit, a shift in
assets to substitute investment vehicles
that are subject to less regulation than
MMFs, and significant impairment of an
important cash-management tool for
investors. Moreover, the economic
importance of risk-taking by MMFs—as
lenders in private debt markets and as
investments that appeal to shareholders’
preferences for risk and return—
suggests that the appropriate objective
for reform should not be to eliminate all
risks posed by MMFs. Attempting to
prevent any fund from ever breaking the
buck would be an impractical goal that
might lead, for example, to draconian
and—from a broad economic
perspective—counterproductive
measures, such as outright prohibitions
on purchases of private debt
instruments and securities with
maturities of more than one day.
Instead, policymakers should balance
the benefits of allowing individual
MMFs to take some risks and facilitating
private and public borrowers’ access to
term financing in money markets with
the broader objective of mitigating
systemic risks—in particular, the risk
that one fund’s problems may cause
serious harm to other MMFs, their
shareholders, short-term funding
markets, the financial system, and the
economy.
a. SEC Regulatory Changes
In January 2010, the SEC adopted new
rules regulating MMFs in order to make
these funds more resilient to market
to facilitate an orderly and timely liquidation of the
fund. Under the agreement, Treasury would
purchase certain securities issued by government
sponsored enterprises at amortized cost (not mark
to market), and $3.6 billion of such purchases were
completed in January 2009.
E:\FR\FM\08NON1.SGM
08NON1
Federal Register / Vol. 75, No. 215 / Monday, November 8, 2010 / Notices
jlentini on DSKJ8SOYB1PROD with NOTICES
disruptions and thus less likely to break
the buck. The new rules also might help
reduce the likelihood of runs on MMFs
by facilitating the orderly liquidation of
funds that have broken the buck. The
SEC designed the new rules primarily to
meet its statutory obligations under the
ICA to protect investors and promote
capital formation. Nonetheless, the rules
should mitigate (although not eliminate)
systemic risks by reducing the
susceptibility of MMFs to runs, both by
lessening the likelihood that an
individual fund will break the buck and
by containing the damage should one
break the buck. The rule changes fall
into three principal categories.
(i) Enhanced Risk-Limiting
Constraints on Money Market Fund
Portfolios. Each of the changes that
follow further constrains risk-taking by
MMFs.
Liquidity Risk. One of the most
important SEC rule changes aimed at
reducing systemic risk associated with
MMFs is a requirement that each fund
maintain a substantial liquidity cushion.
Augmented liquidity should position
MMFs to better withstand heavy
redemptions without selling portfolio
securities into potentially distressed
markets at discounted prices. Forced
‘‘fire sales’’ to meet heavy redemptions
may cause losses not only for the fund
that must sell the securities, but also for
other MMFs that hold the same or
similar securities. Thus, a substantial
liquidity cushion should help reduce
the risk that strains on one MMF will be
transmitted to other funds and to shortterm credit markets.
Specifically, the SEC’s new rules
require that MMFs maintain minimum
daily and weekly liquidity positions.
Daily liquidity, which must be at least
10 percent of a MMF’s assets, includes
cash, U.S. Treasury obligations, and
securities (including repurchase
agreements) that mature or for which
the fund has a contractual right to
obtain cash within a day. Weekly
liquidity, which must be at least 30
percent of each MMF’s assets, includes
cash, securities that mature or can be
converted to cash within a week, U.S.
Treasury obligations, and securities
issued by federal government agencies
and government-sponsored enterprises
with remaining maturities of 60 days or
less.17 Furthermore, the new rules
17 Tax-exempt money market funds are exempt
from daily minimum liquidity requirements but not
the weekly minimum liquidity requirements,
because most tax-exempt fund portfolios consist of
longer-term floating- and variable-rate securities
with seven-day ‘‘put’’ options that effectively give
the funds weekly liquidity. Tax-exempt funds are
unlikely to have investment alternatives that would
permit them to meet a daily liquidity requirement.
VerDate Mar<15>2010
18:02 Nov 05, 2010
Jkt 223001
require MMF advisers to maintain larger
liquidity buffers as necessary to meet
reasonably foreseeable redemptions.
Credit Risk. The new rules reduce
MMFs’ maximum allowable holdings of
‘‘second-tier’’ securities, which carry
more credit risk than first-tier securities,
to no more than 3 percent of each fund’s
assets.18 In addition, a MMF’s exposure
to a single second-tier issuer is now
limited to one-half of 1 percent of the
fund’s assets, and funds can only
purchase second-tier securities with
maturities of 45 days or less. These new
constraints reduce the likelihood that
individual funds will be exposed to a
credit event that could cause the funds
to break the buck. Also, since secondtier securities often trade in thinner
markets, these changes should improve
the ability of individual MMFs to
maintain a stable NAV during periods of
market volatility.
Interest Rate Risk. By reducing the
maximum allowable weighted average
maturity (WAM) of fund portfolios from
90 days to 60 days, the new rules are
intended to diminish funds’ exposure to
interest rate risk and increase the
liquidity of fund portfolios. The SEC
also introduced a new weighted average
life (WAL) measure for MMFs—and set
a ceiling for WAL at 120 days—in order
to lower funds’ exposure to interest-rate,
credit, and liquidity risks associated
with the floating-rate obligations that
MMFs commonly hold.19
Stress Testing. Finally, the SEC’s new
rules require fund advisers to
periodically stress test their funds’
ability to maintain a stable NAV per
share based on certain hypothetical
events, including a change in short-term
interest rates, an increase in shareholder
redemptions, a downgrade or default of
a portfolio security, and a change in
interest rate spreads. Regular and
methodical monitoring of these risks
and their potential effects should help
funds weather stress without incident.
(ii) Facilitating Orderly Fund
Liquidations. The new SEC rules should
18 Under SEC rule 2a–7, for short-term debt
securities to qualify as second-tier securities, they
generally must have received the second highest
short-term debt rating from the credit rating
agencies or be of comparable quality. Section 939A
of the Dodd-Frank Act requires that government
agencies remove references to credit ratings in their
rules and replace them with other credit standards
that the agency determines appropriate. As a result,
the SEC will be reconsidering this rule and its
provisions relating to second-tier securities to
comply with this statutory mandate.
19 For purposes of computing WAM, a floatingrate security’s ‘‘maturity’’ can be its next interestrate reset date. In computing WAL, the life of a
security is determined solely by its final maturity
date. Hence, WAL should be more useful than
WAM in reflecting the risks of widening spreads on
longer-term floating-rate securities.
PO 00000
Frm 00050
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
68645
reduce the systemic risk posed by
MMFs by permitting a fund that is
breaking the buck to promptly suspend
redemptions and liquidate its portfolio
in an orderly manner. This new rule
should help prevent a capital loss at one
fund from forcing a disorderly sale of
portfolio securities that might disrupt
short-term markets and diminish share
values of other MMFs. Moreover, the
ability of a fund to suspend redemptions
should help prevent investors who
redeem shares from benefiting at the
expense of those who remain invested
in a fund.
(iii) Repurchase Agreements. The
SEC’s new rules place more stringent
constraints on repurchase agreements
that are collateralized with private debt
instruments rather than cash
equivalents or government securities.
MMFs are among the largest purchasers
of repurchase agreements, which they
use to invest cash, typically on an
overnight basis. Because the collateral
usually consists of long-term debt
securities, a MMF cannot hold the
securities underlying this collateral
without violating SEC rules that limit
MMF holdings to short-term obligations.
Accordingly, if a significant
counterparty fails to repurchase
securities as stipulated in a repurchase
agreement, its MMF counterparties can
be expected to direct custodians to sell
the collateral immediately, and sales of
private debt instruments could be
sizable and disruptive to financial
markets. To address this risk, the SEC’s
new rule places additional constraints
on MMFs’ exposure to counterparties
through repurchase agreement
transactions that are collateralized by
securities other than cash equivalents or
government securities.
b. Need for Further Reform To Reduce
Susceptibility to Runs
The new SEC rules make MMFs more
resilient and less risky and therefore
reduce the likelihood of runs on funds,
increase the size of runs that they could
withstand, and mitigate the systemic
risks they pose. However, more can be
done to address the structural
vulnerabilities of MMFs to runs. Indeed,
the Chairman of the SEC characterized
its new rules as ‘‘a first step’’ in
strengthening MMFs and noted that a
number of additional possible reforms
(many of which are presented in section
3 of this report) are under discussion.
Likewise, Treasury’s Financial
Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
(2009) anticipated that measures taken
by the SEC ‘‘should not, by themselves,
be expected to prevent a run on MMFs
of the scale experienced in September
2008.’’
E:\FR\FM\08NON1.SGM
08NON1
jlentini on DSKJ8SOYB1PROD with NOTICES
68646
Federal Register / Vol. 75, No. 215 / Monday, November 8, 2010 / Notices
Of the five features that make MMFs
vulnerable to runs (see section 1(b)), the
two most directly addressed in the new
SEC rules are liquidity risks associated
with maturity transformation and MMF
portfolios’ exposures to credit and
interest-rate risks. The SEC’s new rules
should substantially reduce these risks,
but systemic risks arising from the other
features of MMFs and their investors—
the stable, rounded NAV, a system of
discretionary sponsor support, and a
highly risk-averse investor base—still
remain, as do many of the amplifying
interaction effects. Some mitigation of
the destabilizing effects that one or a
few MMFs can impose on the rest of the
industry through contagion might be
achievable through further
modifications to rule 2a–7 and other
SEC rules. Importantly, however, other
reforms that could more substantially
reduce the risk of contagion and that, as
such, merit further consideration, would
require action beyond what the SEC
could achieve under its current
authority.
Mitigating the risk of runs before
another liquidity crisis materializes is
especially important because the events
of September 2008 may have induced
expectations of government assistance at
minimal cost in case of severe financial
strains. Market participants know, and
recent events have confirmed, that when
runs on MMFs occur, the government
will face substantial pressure to
intervene in some manner to minimize
the propagation of financial strains to
short-term funding markets and to the
real economy. Importantly, such
interventions would be intended not
only to reduce harm to MMF investors
but also to prevent disruptions of
markets for commercial paper and other
short-term financing instruments, which
are critical for the functioning of the
economy. Therefore, if further measures
to insulate the industry from systemic
risk are not taken before the next
liquidity crisis, market participants will
likely expect that the government would
provide emergency support at minimal
cost for MMFs during the next crisis.
Such market expectations of
(hypothetical) future non-priced or
subsidized government support would
distort incentives for MMFs and prices
in short-term funding markets and
would potentially increase the systemic
risk posed by MMFs. To forestall these
perverse effects, it is thus imperative
that MMFs be required to internalize
fully the costs of liquidity or other risks
associated with their operation.
MMF regulatory reform in light of the
run on MMFs in September and October
2008. The run on MMFs in 2008
provides some important lessons for
VerDate Mar<15>2010
18:02 Nov 05, 2010
Jkt 223001
evaluating potential reforms for
mitigating systemic risk. For example,
the triggering events of the run and the
magnitude of the outflows that followed
underscore the difficulty of designing
reforms that might prevent runs and the
associated damage to the financial
system.
Making each individual MMF robust
enough to survive a crisis of the size of
that experienced in 2008 may not be an
appropriate policy objective because it
would unduly limit risk taking. Indeed,
although the SEC’s tightening of
restrictions on the liquidity, interestrate, and credit risks borne by
individual MMFs will be helpful in
making MMFs more resilient to future
strains, there are practical limits to the
degree of systemic risk mitigation that
can be achieved through further
restrictions of this type. For example, an
objective of preventing any MMF from
breaking the buck probably would not
be feasible for funds that invest in
private debt markets. Changes that
would prevent funds from breaking the
buck due to a single Lehman Brotherslike exposure would have to be severe:
Only limiting funds’ exposures to each
issuer to less than one-half of 1 percent
of assets would prevent a precipitous
drop in the value of any single issuer’s
debt from causing a MMF to break the
buck.20 But even such a limit on
exposure to a single issuer would not
address the risk that MMFs may
accumulate exposures to distinct but
highly correlated issuers, and that funds
would remain vulnerable to events that
cause the debt of multiple issuers to lose
value.
Beyond diversification limits, new
rules to protect MMFs from material
credit losses would be difficult to craft
unless regulators take the extreme step
of eliminating funds’ ability to hold any
risky assets. But that approach would be
clearly undesirable, as it would
adversely affect many firms that obtain
short-term financing through
commercial paper and similar
instruments. In addition, such an
extreme approach would deny many
retail investors any opportunity to
obtain exposure to private money
market instruments and most likely
would motivate some institutional
investors to shift assets from MMFs to
less regulated vehicles.
Similarly, liquidity requirements
sufficient to cover all redemption
scenarios for MMFs probably would be
impractical and inefficient. The SEC’s
20 At the time of its bankruptcy, Lehman Brothers’
short-term debt was still a first-tier security, so
MMFs were able to hold up to 5 percent of their
assets in Lehman Brothers’ debt. The SEC’s new
rules do not affect this limit.
PO 00000
Frm 00051
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
new liquidity requirements help
mitigate liquidity risks borne by the
funds, and if MMFs had held enough
liquid assets in September 2008 to meet
the new liquidity requirements, each
MMF would have had adequate daily
liquidity to meet redemption requests
on most individual days during the run.
Even so, the cumulative effect of severe
outflows on consecutive days would
have exceeded many funds’ liquidity
buffers. Moreover, without external
support in 2008—specifically, the
introduction of the Treasury’s
Temporary Guarantee Program for
Money Market Funds and the Federal
Reserve’s AMLF—outflows likely would
have continued and been much larger,
and they would have forced substantial
sales of assets to meet redemptions.
Such asset sales would have contributed
to severe strains in short-term markets,
depressed asset prices, caused capital
losses for MMFs, and prompted further
shareholder flight. Hence, MMFs’
experience during the run in 2008
indicates that the new SEC liquidity
requirements make individual MMFs
more resilient to shocks but still leave
them susceptible to runs of substantial
scale.
Raising the liquidity requirements
enough so that each MMF would hold
adequate daily liquidity to withstand a
large-scale run would be a severe
constraint and would fail to take
advantage of risk-pooling opportunities
that might be exploited by external
sources of liquidity. During the run in
2008, individual MMFs experienced
large variations in the timing and
magnitude of their redemptions.
Liquidity requirements stringent enough
to ensure that every individual MMF
could have met redemptions without
selling assets would have left most of
the industry with far too much liquidity,
even during the run, and would have
created additional liquidity risks for
issuers of short-term securities, since
these issuers would have had to roll
over paper more frequently. Some of the
approaches discussed in section 3 are
aimed at buttressing the SEC’s new
minimum liquidity requirements
without simply increasing their
magnitude.
Finally, the run on MMFs in 2008
demonstrated the systemic threat that
such runs may represent. Without
additional reforms to more fully
mitigate the risk of a run spreading
among MMFs, the actions to support the
MMF industry that the U.S. government
took beginning in 2008 may create an
expectation for similar government
support during future financial crises,
and the resulting moral hazard may
make crises in the MMF industry more
E:\FR\FM\08NON1.SGM
08NON1
Federal Register / Vol. 75, No. 215 / Monday, November 8, 2010 / Notices
frequent than the historical record
would suggest. Accordingly, despite the
risk reduction that should be achieved
by the initial set of new SEC rules,
policymakers should explore the
advantages and disadvantages of
implementing further reforms before
another crisis materializes.
3. Policy Options for Further Reducing
the Risks of Runs on MMFs
This section discusses a range of
options for further mitigation of the
systemic risks posed by MMFs. The SEC
requested comment on some of these
options, such as requiring that MMFs
maintain a floating NAV or requiring in
kind redemptions in certain
circumstances. In addition, the SEC
received comments proposing a two-tier
system of MMFs in which some funds
maintain a stable NAV and others a
floating NAV. Other options discussed
in this section go beyond what the SEC
could implement under existing
authorities and would require
legislation or coordinated action by
multiple government agencies and the
MMF industry. While the measures
presented here, either individually or in
combination, would help diminish
systemic risk, new restrictions imposed
solely on MMFs may reduce their
appeal to some investors and might
cause some—primarily institutional—
investors to move assets to less
regulated cash management substitutes.
Many such funds, like MMFs, seek to
maintain a stable NAV and have other
features that make them vulnerable to
runs, so such funds likely also would
pose systemic risks. Therefore, effective
mitigation of MMFs’ susceptibility to
runs may require policy reforms beyond
those directed at registered MMFs to
address risks posed by funds that
compete with MMFs. Such reforms,
which generally would require
legislation, are discussed in section 3(h).
jlentini on DSKJ8SOYB1PROD with NOTICES
a. Floating Net Asset Values
Historically, the $1 stable NAV that
MMFs maintain under rule 2a–7 has
been a key element of their appeal to a
broad range of investors, and the stable
NAV has contributed to a dramatic
expansion in MMFs’ assets over the past
two decades. At the same time, as noted
in section 1(b), the stable, rounded NAV
is one of the features that heighten the
vulnerability of MMFs to runs. The
significance of MMFs in financial
markets and the central role of the
stable, rounded NAV in making MMFs
appealing to investors and, at the same
time, vulnerable to runs, make careful
discussion of the potential benefits and
risks of moving MMFs away from a
VerDate Mar<15>2010
18:02 Nov 05, 2010
Jkt 223001
stable NAV essential to a discussion of
MMF reform.
The stable, rounded NAVs of MMFs
contribute to their vulnerability to runs
for several reasons.
• First, the stable, rounded NAV,
coupled with MMF sponsors’
longstanding practice of supporting the
stable NAV when funds have
encountered difficulties, has fostered
investors’ expectations that MMF shares
are risk-free cash equivalents. When the
Reserve Primary Fund failed to maintain
those expectations in September 2008,
the sudden loss of investor confidence
helped precipitate a generalized run on
MMFs. By making gains and losses a
regular occurrence, as they are in other
mutual funds, a floating NAV could
alter investor expectations and make
clear that MMFs are not risk-free
vehicles. Thus, investors might become
more accustomed to and tolerant of
NAV fluctuations and less prone to
sudden, destabilizing reactions in the
face of even modest losses. However,
the substantial changes in investor
expectations that could result from a
floating NAV also might motivate
investors to shift assets away from
MMFs to banks or to unregulated cashmanagement vehicles, and the effects of
potentially large movements of assets on
the financial system should be
considered carefully. These issues are
discussed in more detail later.
• Second, a rounded NAV may
accelerate runs by amplifying investors’
incentives to redeem shares quickly if a
fund is at risk of a capital loss. When
a MMF experiences a loss of less than
one-half of 1 percent and continues to
redeem shares at a rounded NAV of $1,
it offers redeeming shareholders an
arbitrage opportunity by paying more
for the shares than the shares are worth.
Simultaneously, the fund drives down
the expected future value of the shares
because redemptions at $1 per share
further erode the fund’s market-based
per-share value—and increase the
likelihood that the fund will break the
buck—as losses on portfolio assets are
spread over a shrinking asset base.
These dynamics are inherently unstable.
Thus, even an investor who otherwise
might not choose to redeem may do so
in recognition of other shareholders’
incentives to redeem and the effects of
such redemptions on a fund’s expected
NAV. The growth of institutional
investment in MMFs has exacerbated
this instability because institutional
investors are better positioned than
retail investors to identify potential
problems in a MMF’s portfolio and
rapidly withdraw significant amounts of
assets from the fund.
PO 00000
Frm 00052
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
68647
In contrast, a floating NAV eliminates
some of the incentives to redeem when
a MMF has experienced a loss. Because
MMFs must redeem shares at NAVs set
after redemption requests are received,
losses incurred by a fund with a floating
NAV are borne on a pro rata basis by all
shareholders, whether they redeem or
not. Redemptions from such a fund do
not concentrate already incurred losses
over a smaller asset base and do not
create clear arbitrage opportunities for
investors. However, as discussed below,
a floating NAV does not eliminate the
incentive to redeem shares from a
distressed MMF.
• Third, the SEC rules that permit
funds to maintain a stable, rounded
NAV also force an abrupt decrease in
price once the difference between a
fund’s market-based shadow NAV and
its $1 stable NAV exceeds one-half of 1
percent. So, although NAV fluctuations
are rare in MMFs, when prices do
decline, the change appears as a sudden
drop. This discontinuity heightens
investors’ incentives to redeem shares
before a loss is incurred, produces dire
headlines, and probably raises the
chance of a panic.
These considerations suggest that
moving to a floating NAV would reduce
the systemic risk posed by MMFs to
some extent. Under a required floating
NAV, MMFs would have to value their
portfolio assets just like any other
mutual fund. That is, MMFs would not
be able to round their NAVs to $1 or use
the accounting methods (for example,
amortized cost for portfolio securities
with a maturity of greater than 60 days)
currently allowed under rule 2a–7.
To be sure, a floating NAV itself
would not eliminate entirely MMFs’
susceptibility to runs. Rational investors
still would have an incentive to redeem
as fast as possible the shares of any
MMF that is at risk of depleting its
liquidity buffer before that buffer is
exhausted, because subsequent
redemptions may force the fund to
dispose of less-liquid assets and incur
losses. However, investors would have
less of an incentive to run from MMFs
with floating NAVs than from those
with stable, rounded NAVs.
Notwithstanding the advantages of a
floating NAV, elimination of the stable
NAV for MMFs would be a dramatic
change for a nearly $3 trillion assetmanagement sector that has been built
around the stable $1 share price. Indeed,
a switch to floating NAVs for MMFs
raises several concerns.
• First, such a change might reduce
investor demand for MMFs and thus
diminish their capacity to supply credit
to businesses, financial institutions,
state and local governments, and other
E:\FR\FM\08NON1.SGM
08NON1
68648
Federal Register / Vol. 75, No. 215 / Monday, November 8, 2010 / Notices
jlentini on DSKJ8SOYB1PROD with NOTICES
borrowers who obtain financing in
short-term debt markets. MMFs are the
dominant providers of some types of
credit, such as commercial paper and
short-term municipal debt, so a
significant contraction of MMFs might
cause particular difficulties for
borrowers who rely on these
instruments for financing. If the
contraction were abrupt, redemptions
might cause severe disruptions for
MMFs, the markets for the instruments
the funds hold, and borrowers who tap
those markets. While there is no direct
evidence on the likely effect of a floating
NAV on the demand for MMFs, the risk
of a substantial shift of assets away from
MMFs and into other vehicles should be
weighed carefully. Assets under
management in MMFs dwarf those of
their nearest substitutes, such as, for
example, ultra-short bond funds, most
likely because ultra-short bond funds
are not viewed as cash substitutes. To
the extent that demand for stable NAV
funds is boosted by investors who hold
MMFs because they perceive them to be
risk-free, a reduction in demand for
these funds might be desirable.21
However, some investors face functional
obstacles to placing certain assets in
floating NAV funds. For example,
internal investment guidelines may
prevent corporate cash managers from
investing in floating NAV funds, some
state laws allow municipalities to invest
only in stable-value funds, and fiduciary
obligations may prevent institutional
investors from investing client money in
floating NAV funds. In addition, some
investors may not tolerate the loss of
accounting convenience and tax
efficiencies that would result from a
shift to a floating NAV, although these
problems might be mitigated somewhat
through regulatory or legislative
actions.22
• Second, a related concern is that
elimination of MMFs’ stable NAVs may
cause investors to shift assets to stable
NAV substitutes that are vulnerable to
runs but subject to less regulation than
MMFs. In particular, many institutional
investors might move assets to less
regulated or unregulated cash
21 Even a contraction in the credit extended by
MMFs might be an efficient outcome if such credit
has been over-supplied because markets have not
priced liquidity and systemic risks appropriately.
22 A stable NAV relieves shareholders of the
administrative task of tracking the timing and price
of purchase and sale transactions for tax and
accounting purposes. For investors using MMFs for
cash management, floating NAV funds (under
current rules) would present more record-keeping
requirements than stable NAV funds, although
certain tax changes beginning in 2011 will require
mutual funds, including MMFs, to report the tax
basis (presumably using an average basis method)
to shareholders and thereby help reduce any
associated accounting burden from a floating NAV.
VerDate Mar<15>2010
18:02 Nov 05, 2010
Jkt 223001
management vehicles, such as offshore
MMFs, enhanced cash funds, and other
stable value vehicles that hold portfolios
similar to those of MMFs but are not
subject to the ICA’s restrictions on
MMFs. These unregistered funds can
take on more risks than MMFs, but such
risks are not necessarily transparent to
investors. Accordingly, unregistered
funds may pose even greater systemic
risks than MMFs, particularly if new
restrictions on MMFs prompt
substantial growth in unregistered
funds. Thus, changes to MMF rules
might displace or even increase
systemic risks, rather than mitigate
them, and make such risks more
difficult to monitor and control.
Reforms designed to reduce risks in less
regulated or unregulated MMF
substitutes are discussed in more detail
in section 3(h).
Elimination of MMFs’ stable NAVs
may also prompt some investors—
particularly retail investors—to shift
assets from MMFs to banks. Such asset
shifts would have potential benefits and
drawbacks, which are discussed in some
detail in section 3(g).
• Third, MMFs’ transition from stable
to floating NAVs might itself be
systemically risky. For example, if
shareholders perceive a risk that a fund
that is maintaining a $1 NAV under
current rules has a market-based
shadow NAV of less than $1, these
investors may redeem shares
preemptively to avoid potential losses
when MMFs switch to floating NAVs.
Shareholders who cannot tolerate
floating NAVs probably also would
redeem in advance. If large enough,
redemptions could force some funds to
sell assets and make concerns about
losses self-fulfilling. Hence, successful
implementation of a switch to floating
NAVs would depend on careful design
of the conversion process to guard
against destabilizing transition
dynamics.
• Fourth, risk management practices
in a floating NAV MMF industry might
deteriorate without the discipline
required to maintain a $1 share price.
MMFs comply with rule 2a–7 because
doing so gives them the ability to use
amortized-cost accounting to maintain a
stable NAV. Without this reward, the
incentive to follow 2a–7 restrictions is
less clear. Moreover, the stable, rounded
NAV creates a bright line for fund
advisers: Losses in excess of 1⁄2 of 1
percent would be catastrophic because
they would cause a fund to break the
buck. With a floating NAV, funds would
not have as clear a tipping point, so
fund advisers might face reduced
incentives for prudent risk management.
PO 00000
Frm 00053
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
• The fifth and final concern is that
a floating NAV that accomplishes its
proponents’ objectives of reducing
systemic risks may be difficult to
implement. Under normal market
conditions, even a floating NAV would
likely move very little because of the
nature of MMF assets. For example,
although a requirement that MMFs
move to a $10 NAV and round to the
nearest cent would force funds to
reprice shares for as little as a 5 basis
point change in portfolio value, NAV
fluctuations might still remain relatively
rare. Enhanced precision for NAVs (for
example, NAVs with five significant
figures) could bring more regular,
incremental fluctuations, but precise
pricing of many money market
securities is challenging given the
absence of active secondary markets. In
addition, if fund sponsors decided to
provide support to offset any small
deviations from the usual NAV,
deviations from that NAV might remain
rare.
Thus, a floating NAV may not
substantially improve investors’
understanding of the riskiness of MMFs
or reduce the stigma and systemic risks
associated with breaking the buck.
Investors’ perceptions that MMFs are
virtually riskless may change slowly
and unpredictably if NAV fluctuations
remain small and rare. MMFs with
floating NAVs, at least temporarily,
might even be more prone to runs if
investors who continue to see shares as
essentially risk-free react to small or
temporary changes in the value of their
shares.
To summarize, requiring the entire
MMF industry to move to a floating
NAV would have some potential
benefits, but those benefits would have
to be weighed carefully against the risks
that such a change would entail.
b. Private Emergency Liquidity
Facilities for MMFs
As discussed in section 1(b), the
liquidity risk of MMFs contributes
importantly to MMFs’ vulnerability to
runs. The programs introduced at the
height of the run on MMFs in
September 2008—Treasury’s Temporary
Guarantee Program for Money Market
Funds and the liquidity backstop
provided by the AMLF—were effective
in stopping the run on MMFs.23 More
generally, policymakers have long
recognized the utility of liquidity
23 Outflows from prime MMFs totaled about $200
billion in the two days prior to the Treasury and
Federal Reserve announcements on Friday,
September 19, 2008. However, in the two business
days following the announcements (Monday and
Tuesday, September 22 and 23), outflows were just
$22 billion.
E:\FR\FM\08NON1.SGM
08NON1
Federal Register / Vol. 75, No. 215 / Monday, November 8, 2010 / Notices
jlentini on DSKJ8SOYB1PROD with NOTICES
backstops for institutions engaged in
maturity transformation: Banks, for
example, have had access to the
discount window since its inception,
and backstop lending facilities also have
been created more recently for other
types of institutions. Thus, enhanced
liquidity protection should be
considered as part of any regulatory
reform effort aimed at preventing runs
on MMFs. At the same time, such
enhanced liquidity protection does not
have to be provided necessarily by the
government: A private facility,
adequately capitalized and financed by
the MMF industry, could be set up to
supply liquidity to funds that most need
it at times of market stress. Depending
on its structure, such a private facility
itself might have access to broader
liquidity backstops.
A private emergency liquidity facility
could be beneficial on several levels.
First, a private liquidity facility, in
combination with the SEC’s new
liquidity requirements, might
substantially buttress MMFs’ ability to
withstand outflows without selling
assets in potentially illiquid markets.24
Second, a private emergency facility
might offer important efficiency gains
from risk pooling. Even during the
systemic liquidity crisis in 2008,
individual MMFs experienced large
variations in the timing and magnitude
of redemptions. An emergency facility
could provide liquidity to the MMFs
that need it; in contrast, liquidity
requirements for individual MMFs
would likely leave some funds with too
much liquidity and others with too
little. Third, a private liquidity facility
might provide funds with flexibility in
managing liquidity risks if, for example,
regulators allowed MMFs some relief in
liquidity requirements in return for the
funds’ purchase of greater access to the
liquidity facility’s capacity.
Importantly, a properly designed and
well-managed private liquidity facility
would internalize the cost of liquidity
protection for the MMF industry and
24 For example, as noted in the text, even if MMFs
in September 2008 had held liquid assets in the
proportions that the SEC has recently mandated, the
net redemptions experienced by the funds
following the Lehman Brothers bankruptcy would
have forced MMFs to sell considerable amounts of
securities into illiquid markets in the absence of the
substantial government interventions. But a
liquidity facility with the capacity to provide an
additional 10 percent overnight liquidity to each
fund would double the effective overnight liquid
resources available to MMFs. If MMFs in September
2008 had already been in compliance with the new
liquidity requirements, a facility with this capacity
would have considerably reduced funds’ need to
raise liquidity (for example, through asset sales)
during the run. In addition, the very existence of
the facility might have reduced redemption requests
in the first place.
VerDate Mar<15>2010
18:02 Nov 05, 2010
Jkt 223001
provide appropriate incentives for
MMFs and their investors.25 Such a
facility would not help funds that take
on excessive capital risks or face runs
because of isolated credit losses (a welldesigned private liquidity facility would
not have helped the Reserve Primary
Fund or its shareholders avoid losses in
September 2008 due to holdings of
Lehman Brothers debt). Moreover, a
liquidity facility alone may not prevent
runs on MMFs triggered by concerns
about more widespread credit losses at
MMFs. However, a liquidity facility
could substantially reduce the damage
that a run on a single distressed fund
might cause to the rest of the industry.
While a private emergency liquidity
facility would be appealing in several
respects, setting up an effective facility
would present a number of challenges.
The structure and operations of a
private liquidity facility would have to
be considered carefully to ensure that it
would be effective during crises and
that it would not unduly distort
incentives, while, at the same time, that
it would be in compliance with all
applicable regulations and that it would
not favor certain market participants or
business models. For example:
• On the one hand, if MMFs were
required to participate in a private
facility, regulators would assume some
responsibility for ensuring that the
facility was operated equitably and
efficiently, that it managed risks
prudently, and that it was able to
provide liquidity effectively during a
crisis. On the other hand, if
participation were voluntary, some
MMFs would likely choose not to
participate to avoid sharing in the costs
associated with the facility. Nonparticipating MMFs might present
greater risks than their competitors but
would free-ride on the stability the
liquidity facility would provide. In a
voluntary participation framework, one
means of balancing risks between MMFs
that do and do not participate in a
liquidity facility would be to require
nonparticipants to adhere to more
stringent risk-limiting constraints or to
require such funds to switch to a
floating NAV. Such an approach (in
which some MMFs have stable NAVs
and others floating NAVs) is considered
in section 3(e).
• Ensuring that the facility has
adequate capacity to meet MMFs’
liquidity needs during a crisis would be
critical to the effectiveness of the facility
in mitigating systemic risk. Inadequate
25 A private liquidity facility could also result in
retail fund investors bearing some of the costs of
meeting the likely higher liquidity needs of
institutional funds. Consideration should be given
as to whether and how to prevent such an outcome.
PO 00000
Frm 00054
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
68649
capacity might, for example, create an
incentive for MMF advisers to tap the
facility before others do and thus make
the facility itself vulnerable to runs.
News of a depleted liquidity facility
might amplify investor concerns and
trigger or expand a run on MMFs.
However, raising enough capital to
build adequate liquidity capacity
without undue leverage would be a
challenge for the asset management
industry. Accordingly, meaningful
mitigation of systemic risk may require
that the facility itself have access to
alternative sources of liquidity.
• A private facility may face conflicts
of interest during a crisis when liquidity
is in short supply. Responsibility to the
facility’s shareholders would mandate
prudence in providing liquidity to
MMFs. For example, facility managers
would want to be selective in providing
liquidity against term commercial paper
out of concern about losses on such
paper. However, excessive prudence
would be at odds with the facility
serving as an effective liquidity
backstop. In addition, a private facility
may face conflicts among different types
of shareholders and participants who
may have different interests, and a
strong governance structure would be
needed to address these conflicts as well
as prevent the domination of the facility
by the advisers of larger funds.
• Rules governing access to the
facility would have to be crafted
carefully to minimize the moral hazard
problems among fund advisers, who
could face diminished incentives to
maintain liquidity in their MMFs.
However, excessive constraints on
access would limit the facility’s
effectiveness. An appropriate balancing
of access rules might be difficult to
achieve.
Notwithstanding these concerns, a
private emergency liquidity facility
could play an important role in
supplementing the SEC’s new liquidity
requirements for MMFs. The potential
advantages and disadvantages of such a
facility, as well as its optimal structure
and modes of operation, should be the
subjects of further analysis and
discussion.
c. Mandatory Redemptions in Kind
When investors make large
redemptions from MMFs, they impose
liquidity costs on other shareholders in
the fund. For example, redemptions
may force a fund to sell its most liquid
assets to raise cash. Remaining
shareholders are left with claims on a
less liquid portfolio, so redemptions are
particularly costly for other
E:\FR\FM\08NON1.SGM
08NON1
68650
Federal Register / Vol. 75, No. 215 / Monday, November 8, 2010 / Notices
jlentini on DSKJ8SOYB1PROD with NOTICES
shareholders during a crisis, when
liquidity is most valued.26
A requirement that MMFs distribute
large redemptions by institutional
investors in kind, rather than in cash,
would force these redeeming
shareholders to bear their own liquidity
costs and reduce their incentive to
redeem.27 If liquidity pressures are
causing money market instruments to
trade at discounts, a MMF that
distributes a large redemption in cash
may have to sell securities at a discount
to raise the cash. All shareholders in the
fund would share in the loss on a pro
rata basis. However, if the fund
distributes securities to the investor in
proportion to the claim on the fund
represented by the redeemed shares, the
liquidity risk would be borne most
directly by the redeeming investor. If
the fund elects to dispose of the
securities in a dislocated market and
incurs a loss, other shareholders are not
directly affected.28
Requiring large redemptions to be
made in kind would reduce, but not
eliminate the systemic risk associated
with large, widespread redemptions.
Shareholders with immediate liquidity
needs who receive securities from
MMFs would have to sell those assets,
and the consequences for short-term
markets of such sales would be similar
to the effects if the money market fund
itself had sold the securities. Smaller
shareholders would still receive cash
redemptions, and larger investors might
structure their MMF investments and
redemptions to remain under the inkind threshold.
An in-kind redemption requirement
would present some operational and
policy challenges. Portfolio holdings of
MMFs sometimes are not freely
transferable or are only transferable in
large blocks of shares, so delivery of an
exact pro rata portion of each portfolio
holding to a redeeming shareholder may
be impracticable. Thus, a fund may have
to deliver different securities to different
26 The problem is exacerbated by a rounded NAV,
because a fund that has already incurred a capital
loss but that continues to redeem each share at $1
also transfers capital losses from redeeming
shareholders to those who remain in the fund.
27 Such a requirement also would force redeeming
shareholders to bear their share of any losses that
a MMF has already incurred—even if the fund
maintains a stable, rounded NAV and has not yet
broken the buck—rather than concentrating those
losses entirely in the MMF and thus on remaining
MMF shareholders.
28 If the investor sells securities at a loss,
however, and the MMF also holds the same or
similar securities, the fund may be forced to reprice the securities and lower its mark-to-market,
shadow NAV. So, remaining investors in the fund
may be affected indirectly by the redeeming
investor, even if that investor receives redemptions
in kind.
VerDate Mar<15>2010
18:02 Nov 05, 2010
Jkt 223001
investors but would need to do so in an
equitable manner. Funds should not, for
example, be able to distribute only their
most liquid assets to redeeming
shareholders, since doing so would
undermine the purpose of an in-kind
redemptions requirement. Thus, the
SEC would have to make key judgments
on the circumstances under which a
fund must redeem in kind, as well as
the criteria that funds would use for
determining which portfolio securities
must be distributed and how they
would be valued.
d. Insurance for MMFs
As noted in section 1(b), the absence
of formal capital buffers or insurance for
MMFs, as well as their historical
reliance on discretionary sponsor
support in place of such mechanisms,
further contributes to their vulnerability
to runs. Treasury’s Temporary
Guarantee Program for Money Market
Funds, announced on September 19,
2008, was a key component of the
government intervention that slowed
the run on MMFs. The program
provided guarantees for shares in MMFs
as of the announcement date. These
guarantees were somewhat akin to
deposit insurance, which for many
decades has played a central role in
mitigating the risk of runs on banks.29
Therefore, some form of insurance for
MMF shareholders might be helpful in
mitigating systemic risks posed by
MMFs, although insurance also may
create new risks by distorting incentives
of fund advisers and shareholders.
Like an external liquidity facility,
insurance would reduce the risk of runs
on MMFs, but the consequences of
insurance and a liquidity facility would
otherwise be different. A liquidity
facility would do little or nothing to
help a fund that had already
experienced a capital loss, but such a
facility might be very helpful in
mitigating the destabilizing effects that
one fund’s capital loss might impose on
the rest of the industry. Insurance, in
contrast, would substantially reduce or
eliminate any losses borne by the
shareholders of the MMF that
experienced the capital loss and damp
29 All publicly offered stable NAV MMFs were
eligible to participate in the program. If a MMF
elected to participate, the program guaranteed that
each shareholder in that MMF would receive the
stable share price (typically $1) for each share held
in the fund, up to the number of shares held as of
the close of business on September 19, 2008. In the
event that a participating MMF broke the buck, the
fund was required to suspend redemptions and
commence liquidation, and the fund was eligible to
collect payment from Treasury to enable payment
of the stable share price to each covered investor.
Treasury neither received any claims for payment
nor incurred any losses under the program.
PO 00000
Frm 00055
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
their incentives to redeem shares in that
fund. Although either option might
reduce the incentives for asset managers
and shareholders to minimize risks, a
liquidity facility without an insurance
scheme would leave intact shareholders’
incentive to monitor funds for the credit
and interest rate risks that may trigger
a run. However, in a crisis that triggers
concerns about widespread credit
losses, liquidity protection without
some form of insurance may still leave
MMFs vulnerable to runs.
In addition to these general
considerations, the design and
implementation of an insurance
program for MMFs would require
resolution of a number of difficult
issues. For example:
• Insurance could, in principle, be
provided by the private sector, the
government, or a combination of the
two, but all three options have potential
drawbacks. Private insurers have had
considerable difficulties in fairly pricing
and successfully guaranteeing rare but
high-cost financial events, as
demonstrated, for example, by the
recent difficulties experienced by
financial guarantors. That no private
market for insurance has developed is
some evidence that such insurance for
MMFs may be a challenging business
model, particularly if funds are not
required to obtain insurance.30 Making
insurance for MMFs mandatory could
attract private insurance providers, but
the pricing and scope of coverage that
these providers could offer would need
to be the subject of careful
consideration. In any case, insurers
would need to maintain capital and
carry reinsurance as necessary to cover
losses during extraordinary events.
Public insurance would necessitate new
government oversight and
administration functions and,
particularly in the absence of private
insurance, would require a mechanism
30 The degree of insurance coverage provided by
Treasury’s Temporary Guarantee Program for
Money Market Funds was unprecedented. Private
insurance with considerably narrower coverage has
been available to MMFs in the past: ICI Mutual
Insurance Company, an industry association captive
insurer, offered very limited insurance to MMFs
from 1999 to 2003. This insurance covered losses
on MMF portfolio assets due to defaults and
insolvencies but not losses due to events such as
a security downgrade or a rise in interest rates.
Coverage was limited to $50 million per fund, with
a deductible of the first 10 to 40 basis points of any
loss. Premiums ranged from 1 to 3 basis points. ICI
Mutual reportedly discontinued offering the
insurance in 2003 because coverage restrictions and
other factors limited demand to the point that the
insurance was not providing enough risk pooling to
remain viable. Of course, MMFs continue to have
access to other market-based mechanisms for
transferring risks, such as credit default swaps,
although holdings of such derivative securities by
MMFs are tightly regulated by rule 2a–7.
E:\FR\FM\08NON1.SGM
08NON1
jlentini on DSKJ8SOYB1PROD with NOTICES
Federal Register / Vol. 75, No. 215 / Monday, November 8, 2010 / Notices
for setting appropriate risk-based
premiums (either pre- or post-event). A
hybrid insurance scheme—for example,
with MMFs or their sponsors retaining
the first level of losses up to a threshold,
private insurers or risk pools handling
losses up to a certain higher threshold,
and a government insurance program
serving as a backstop (perhaps with
post-event recoupment)—might offer
some advantages, but it would be
subject to the risks of private insurance
and the challenges of public insurance.
• On the one hand, mandatory
participation in an insurance system
likely would be necessary to instill
investor confidence in the MMF
industry, to ensure an adequate pooling
of risk, to prevent riskier funds from
opting out yet free-riding on the stability
afforded by insured funds, and to create
a sufficient premium base. On the other
hand, an insurance requirement would
create new government responsibilities,
and the regulatory and economic
implications of such a requirement
would have to be evaluated carefully.
• Insurance increases moral hazard
and would shift incentives for prudent
risk management by MMFs from fund
advisers, who are better positioned to
monitor risks, to public or private
insurers. In addition, insurance removes
investors’ incentives to monitor risk
management by fund advisers. Broadly
speaking, insurance fundamentally
changes the nature of MMF shares, from
pooled pass-through investments in
risky assets to insured products with
relatively low yields and limited or no
risk.
• Appropriate pricing would be
critical to the success of a MMF
insurance program, as pricing would
affect the financial position of the
guarantor, the incentives of MMF
advisers, and the relative attractiveness
of different types of MMFs and their
competitors (for example, bank
deposits). Insurance pricing that is not
responsive to the riskiness of individual
MMF portfolios, for example, would
heighten moral hazard problems that
undermine incentives for prudent MMF
risk management. Underpriced
insurance might cause disruptive
outflows from bank deposits to MMFs
and would be a subsidy for sponsors of
and investors in MMFs. Still, insurance
for MMFs might be easier to price fairly
than deposit insurance for banks, as
MMF portfolios are highly restricted,
relatively homogeneous in comparison
with bank portfolios, transparent, and
priced on a daily basis.
• Limits on insurance coverage
(perhaps similar to those for deposit
insurance) would be needed to avoid
giving MMFs an advantage over banks
VerDate Mar<15>2010
18:02 Nov 05, 2010
Jkt 223001
and to preserve incentives for large
investors to monitor the risk
management practices at MMFs.
However, such limits would leave most
institutional investors’ shares only
marginally covered by insurance and do
little to reduce their incentive to run
should MMF risks become salient.
e. A Two-Tier System of MMFs, With
Enhanced Protections for Stable NAV
MMFs
Reforms intended to reduce the
systemic risks posed by MMFs might be
particularly effective if they allow
investors some flexibility in choosing
the MMFs that best match their riskreturn preferences. Policymakers might
accommodate a range of preferences by
allowing two types of MMFs to be
regulated under rule 2a–7:
(i) Stable NAV MMFs. These funds
would continue to maintain stable,
rounded NAVs, but they would be
subject to enhanced protections, which
might include some combination of
tighter regulation (such as higher
liquidity standards) and required access
to an external liquidity backstop. Other
options to provide enhanced protection
for stable NAV funds might include
mandatory distribution of large
redemptions in kind and insurance.
(Policymakers may also consider
limiting the risk arising from investors
in stable NAV funds by restricting sales
of such funds’ shares to retail investors,
as discussed in section 3(f).)
(ii) Floating NAV funds. Although
these MMFs would still have to comply
with many of the current restrictions of
rule 2a–7, these restrictions might be
somewhat less stringent than those for
stable NAV funds. So, floating NAV
funds could bear somewhat greater
credit and liquidity risks than stable
NAV funds, might not be required to
obtain access to external sources of
liquidity or insurance, and most likely
would pay higher yields than their
stable NAV counterparts. Regulatory
relief—for example, allowing simplified
tax treatment for small NAV changes in
funds that adhere to rule 2a–7—might
help preserve the attractiveness of such
funds for many investors.
A two-tier system could mitigate the
systemic risks that arise from a stable,
rounded NAV, by requiring funds that
maintain a stable NAV to have
additional protections that directly
address some of the features that
contribute to their vulnerability to runs.
At the same time, by preserving stable
NAV funds, such a system would
mitigate the risks of a wholesale shift to
floating NAV funds. For example, a twotier system would diminish the
likelihood of a large-scale exodus from
PO 00000
Frm 00056
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
68651
the MMF industry by investors who
might find a floating NAV MMF
unacceptable.
Floating NAV MMFs would face a
lower risk of runs for the reasons
outlined in section 3(a): Frequent
changes in these funds’ NAVs would
help align investor perceptions and
actual fund risks, and investors would
have reduced incentives to redeem early
in a crisis without a rounded NAV. In
addition, investor sorting might
ameliorate the risk of runs: Under such
a two-tier system, investors who choose
floating NAV funds presumably would
be less risk-averse and more tolerant of
NAV changes than the shareholders of
stable NAV funds.
During a crisis, investors would likely
shift at least some assets from riskier
floating NAV MMFs to stable NAV
MMFs, which would presumably be
safer because of their enhanced
protections. Such flows might be
similar, in some respects, to the asset
flows seen during the September 2008
crisis from prime MMFs to government
MMFs, but a shift between tiers of prime
funds could be less disruptive to shortterm funding markets and the aggregate
supply of credit to private firms than a
flight from prime to government MMFs.
Effective design of a two-tier system
would have to incorporate measures to
ensure that large-scale shifts of assets
among MMFs in crises would not be
disruptive.31
For a two-tier system to be effective
and materially mitigate the risk of runs,
investors would have to fully
understand the difference between the
two types of funds and their associated
risks. Investors who do not make this
distinction might flee indiscriminately
from floating NAV and stable NAV
funds alike; in this case, a two-tier
system would not be effective in
mitigating the risk of runs.
The relative ease or difficulty of
implementing a two-tier system would
depend on the nature of the stable NAV
and floating NAV MMFs that comprise
it. For example, if the stable NAV funds
simply were required to satisfy more
stringent SEC rules governing portfolio
safety, creation of a two-tier system
would be fairly straightforward. A
requirement that stable NAV funds
obtain access to an emergency liquidity
facility would likely make stable NAV
31 If stable NAV MMFs carried mandatory
insurance, some limitations on insurance coverage
(for example, stipulating that individual shares in
such funds could be insured only after a given
number of days) might reduce the magnitude of
flows between different types of MMFs and reduce
implicit subsidies for investors who purchase
shares in stable NAV funds only during crises.
However, such rules might diminish the value of
insurance in preventing runs.
E:\FR\FM\08NON1.SGM
08NON1
68652
Federal Register / Vol. 75, No. 215 / Monday, November 8, 2010 / Notices
jlentini on DSKJ8SOYB1PROD with NOTICES
funds less prone to runs and would
reduce the likelihood that investors flee
indiscriminately from both types of
funds in the event of severe market
strains. However, this approach also
would face the challenges associated
with the creation of an effective
liquidity facility (discussed in more
detail in section 3(b)).
f. A Two-Tier System of MMFs, With
Stable NAV MMFs Reserved for Retail
Investors
Another approach to the two-tier
system described in section 3(e) could
distinguish stable NAV and floating
NAV funds by investor type. Stable
NAV MMFs could be made available
only to retail investors, while
institutional investors would be
restricted to floating NAV funds.
This approach would bring enhanced
protections to stable NAV MMFs by
mitigating the risk arising from the
behavior of their investors, because
institutional investors have historically
generated greater risks of runs for MMFs
than retail investors. As noted
previously, the run from MMFs in
September 2008 was primarily a flight
by institutional investors. More than 90
percent of the net outflows from prime
MMFs in the week following the
Lehman Brothers bankruptcy came from
institutional funds, and institutional
investors withdrew substantial sums
from prime MMFs even before the
Reserve Primary Fund broke the buck.
Moreover, evidence suggests that the
additional risks posed by institutional
investors during the run on MMFs in
September 2008 were not unique to that
episode. Relative to retail investors,
institutional investors have greater
resources to monitor MMF portfolios
and risks and have larger amounts at
stake, and are therefore quicker to
redeem shares on concerns about MMF
risks. Institutional MMFs typically have
greater cash flow volatility than retail
funds. Net flows to institutional MMFs
have also exhibited patterns indicating
that institutional investors regularly
arbitrage small discrepancies between
MMFs’ shadow NAVs and their $1 share
prices.32 These observations suggest that
many institutional investors are aware
of such discrepancies—which are likely
to widen during financial crises—and
are able to exploit them.
A two-tier system based on investor
type would protect the interests of retail
investors by reducing the likelihood that
a run might begin in institutional MMFs
32 For example, after Federal Open Market
Committee (FOMC) actions that lower the FOMC’s
target for the federal funds rate, MMF shadow
NAVs rise and institutional MMFs often experience
large net inflows.
VerDate Mar<15>2010
18:02 Nov 05, 2010
Jkt 223001
(as it did in September 2008) and spread
to retail funds. Moreover, such a system
would preserve the original purpose of
MMFs, which was to provide retail
investors with cost-effective access to
diversified investments in money
market instruments. Retail investors
have few alternative opportunities to
obtain such exposures. In contrast,
institutional investors, which can meet
minimum investment thresholds for
direct investments in money market
instruments, would be able to continue
doing so.
One advantage of this alternative is
that it could be accomplished by SEC
rulemaking under existing authorities
without establishing additional market
structures. A prohibition on
institutional investors’ use of stable
NAV MMFs would have some practical
hurdles, however. Successful
enforcement of the rule would require
the SEC to define who would qualify as
retail and institutional investors. In
practice, such distinctions may be
difficult, although not impossible, to
make. For example, retail investors who
own MMF shares because of their
participation in defined contribution
plans (such as 401(k) plans) may be
invested in institutional MMFs through
omnibus accounts that are overseen by
institutional investors (plan
administrators). Simple rules that might
be used to identify institutional
investors, such as defining as
institutional any investor whose
account size exceeds a certain
threshold, would be imperfect and
could motivate the use of workarounds
(such as brokered accounts) by
institutional investors. The SEC, as part
of its rulemaking, would need to take
steps to prevent such workarounds.
Because many institutional investors
may be particularly unwilling to switch
to floating NAV MMFs, a prohibition on
sales of stable NAV MMFs shares to
such investors may have many of the
same unintended consequences as a
requirement that all MMFs adopt
floating NAVs (see section 3(a)). In
particular, prohibiting institutional
investors from holding stable NAV
funds might cause large shifts in assets
to unregulated MMF substitutes. This
concern is of particular importance
given that institutional MMFs currently
account for almost two-thirds of the
assets under management in MMFs.
In addition, a two-tier system based
on investor type would preclude some
of the advantages of allowing
institutional investors to choose
between stable NAV MMFs and floating
NAV MMFs (as the option described in
section 3(e) would permit). For
example, under the two-tier system
PO 00000
Frm 00057
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
described in section 3(e), investor
sorting would provide some protection
for the floating NAV funds, because
institutional investors holding floating
NAV MMFs likely would be less riskaverse than those who held stable NAV
funds. With institutional investors
prohibited from holding shares in stable
NAV MMFs, such sorting among these
investors would not occur. During a
crisis, under the system described in
section 3(e), institutional investors
might be expected to shift assets from
floating NAV MMFs to stable NAV
funds, but a ban on institutional
holdings of stable NAV MMF shares
would prevent such shifts.
g. Regulating Stable NAV MMFs as
Special Purpose Banks
Functional similarities between MMF
shares and deposits, as well as the risk
of runs on both types of instruments,
provide a rationale for introducing
bank-like regulation for MMFs. For
example, mandating that stable NAV
MMFs be reorganized as SPBs might
subject these MMFs to banking
oversight and regulation, including
requirements for reserves and capital
buffers, and provide MMFs with access
to a liquidity backstop and insurance
coverage within a regulatory framework
specifically designed for mitigation of
systemic risk.33 If each MMF were
offered the option of implementing a
floating NAV as an alternative to
reorganizing as a bank, the
reorganization requirement for stable
NAV MMFs might be viewed as part of
a two-tier system for MMFs.34
Although the conceptual basis for
converting stable NAV MMFs to SPBs is
seemingly straightforward, in practice
this option spans a broad range of
possible implementations, most of
which would require legislative changes
and complex interagency regulatory
coordination. The advantages and
disadvantages of this reform option
depend on how exactly the conversion
to SPBs would be implemented and
33 Such an approach to MMF reform was
advocated by the Group of Thirty. See Group of
Thirty, Financial Reform: A Framework for
Financial Stability, released on January 15, 2009.
34 There may be a question as to whether floating
NAV MMFs—if such funds are offered—should or
should not be required to reorganize as SPBs. Other
mutual funds with floating NAVs, such as ultrashort bond funds, presumably would not be affected
by a mandate that MMFs reorganize as SPBs. The
principal distinction between other (non-MMF)
mutual funds and floating NAV MMFs would be
that the latter are constrained by rule 2a–7 and thus
have less risky portfolios, so the advantages and
disadvantages of mandating these funds to
reorganize as banks would have to be carefully
evaluated. However, policymakers could consider
prohibiting floating NAV MMFs from offering banklike services that attract risk-averse investors, such
as the ability to provide transactions services.
E:\FR\FM\08NON1.SGM
08NON1
Federal Register / Vol. 75, No. 215 / Monday, November 8, 2010 / Notices
jlentini on DSKJ8SOYB1PROD with NOTICES
how the new banks would be
structured. A thorough discussion of the
full range of possibilities—including
their feasibility, probable effect on the
MMF industry, broader implications for
the banking system, and likely efficacy
in mitigating systemic risk—would be
quite complex and is beyond the scope
of this report.
As an example of the issues that this
option involves, one possible approach
to its implementation would be to
preserve stable NAV MMFs as
standalone entities but to treat their
shares as deposits for the purposes of
banking law. These shares, unlike other
deposits, might be claims specifically
(and only) on MMF assets, which could
continue to be subject to strict risklimiting regulations such as those
provided by rule 2a–7 or similar rules.
The introduction of such hybrid
investment vehicles would preserve
investors’ opportunity to benefit from
mutualized investments in private
money market instruments, but, being a
novel combination of features of banks
and mutual funds, such vehicles would
also present complex regulatory and
operational challenges. In contrast,
other approaches to converting MMFs to
SPBs, such as absorbing or transforming
stable NAV MMFs into financial
institutions that offer traditional
deposits, might be simpler to
accomplish in practice, but nonetheless
subject to different sets of challenges. In
particular, if the deposits offered by the
new SPBs were only of the types
currently offered by other banks,
investors—and particularly retail
investors, who have few alternative
opportunities to obtain diversified
exposures to money market
instruments—would lose access to
important investment options.35 In
addition, to the extent that banks have
different preferences for portfolio assets
than MMFs, a simple transformation of
MMFs into depository institutions
might lead to a decline in the
availability of short-term financing for
firms and state and local governments
that currently rely on money markets to
satisfy their funding needs.
Considerable further study would thus
be needed in pursuing this option.
Leaving aside the details of how
exactly this option could be
35 In contrast, institutional investors could
continue to obtain such exposures either by
investing directly in money market instruments or
by holding shares in offshore MMFs, enhanced cash
funds, and other stable value vehicles. Hence,
absorption of MMFs by banks might have the
unintended effect of reducing investment
opportunities for retail investors, who generally did
not participate in the run on MMFs in 2008, while
leaving money market investment options for
institutional investors largely intact.
VerDate Mar<15>2010
18:02 Nov 05, 2010
Jkt 223001
implemented, in general terms, a
principal advantage of reorganizing
MMFs as SPBs is that such a change
would provide MMFs with a broad
regulatory framework similar to existing
regulatory systems that are designed for
mitigation of systemic risk. Investments
in MMFs and insured deposits—which
already serve some similar functions,
particularly for retail investors—could
be regulated similarly. MMFs and their
investors might benefit from access to
government insurance and emergency
liquidity facilities at a price similar to
that currently paid by depository
institutions. Importantly, such access
would not require any extraordinary
government actions (such as the
establishment in September 2008 of
Treasury’s Temporary Guarantee
Program for Money Market Funds or the
creation of the Federal Reserve’s
AMLF); instead, the terms of such
access would be codified and wellunderstood in advance.
Moreover, by providing explicit
capital buffers, access to a liquidity
backstop, and deposit insurance, a
conversion of stable NAV MMFs to
SPBs might substantially reduce the
uncertainties and systemic risks
associated with MMF sponsors’ current
practice of discretionary capital support.
Clear rules for how the buffers,
backstop, and insurance would be used
would improve the transparency of the
allocation of risks among market
participants.
However, the capital needed to
reorganize MMFs as SPBs may be a
significant hurdle to successful
implementation of this option. Access to
the Federal Reserve discount window
and deposit insurance coverage most
likely would require that the new SPBs
hold reservable deposits and meet
specific capitalization standards.36
Given the scale of assets under
management in the MMF industry,
MMF sponsors (or banks) that wish to
keep funds operating would have to
raise substantial equity—probably at
least tens of billions of dollars—to meet
regulatory capital requirements.37
36 Currently, MMFs are essentially 100 percent
capital—their liabilities are the equity shares held
by investors—so the meaning of ‘‘capital
requirements’’ for such funds is not clear. However,
if MMFs were reorganized as SPBs, their capital
structure would become more complex. MMF
shares would likely be converted to deposit
liabilities, and MMFs would have to hold
additional capital (equity) buffers to absorb first
losses. Capital requirements would regulate the size
of such buffers.
37 The magnitude of the capital required might be
reduced if floating NAV MMFs were not required
to reorganize as SPBs and if a substantial number
of funds elected to float their NAVs rather than
reorganize as banks. In addition, the capital
required might be reduced somewhat if regulators
PO 00000
Frm 00058
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
68653
Raising such sums would be a
considerable challenge. The asset
management business typically is not
capital intensive, so many asset
managers—and several of the largest
sponsors of MMFs—are lightly
capitalized and probably could not
provide such amounts of capital. If asset
managers or other firms were unwilling
or unable to raise the capital needed to
operate the new SPBs, a sharp reduction
in assets in stable NAV MMFs might
diminish their capacity to supply shortterm credit, curtail the availability of an
attractive investment option
(particularly for retail investors), and
motivate institutional investors to shift
assets to unregulated vehicles.
An additional hurdle to converting
MMFs to SPBs would be the substantial
increase in explicit government
guarantees that would result from the
creation of new insured deposits. The
potential liability to the government
probably would far exceed any
premiums that could be collected for
some time.
Uncertainties about the reaction of
institutional investors to MMFs
reorganized as SPBs raise some
important concerns about whether such
reorganizations would provide a
substantial degree of systemic-risk
mitigation. Coverage limits on deposit
insurance would leave many large
investors unprotected in case of a
significant capital loss. Thus, even with
the protections afforded to banks, MMFs
would still be vulnerable to runs by
institutional investors, unless much
higher deposit insurance limits were
allowed for the newly created SPBs.
Moreover, even in the absence of runs,
institutional MMFs often experience
volatile cash flows, and the potential
effects of large and high-frequency flows
into and out of the banking system (if
MMFs become SPBs) would need to be
analyzed carefully.
The reaction of institutional investors
to the altered set of investment
opportunities may also have unintended
consequences. For example, SPBs that
pay positive net yields to investors
(depositors) would be very attractive for
institutional investors who currently
cannot receive interest on traditional
bank deposits.38 Thus, on the one hand,
the new SPBs might prompt shifts of
assets by institutional investors from the
traditional banking system. On the other
hand, a substantial mandatory capital
determined that the nature of the assets held by
MMFs justifies capital requirements that are lower
than those imposed on commercial banks and
thrifts.
38 Section 627 of the Dodd-Frank Act repeals the
prohibition on banks paying interest on corporate
demand deposit accounts effective July 21, 2011.
E:\FR\FM\08NON1.SGM
08NON1
68654
Federal Register / Vol. 75, No. 215 / Monday, November 8, 2010 / Notices
jlentini on DSKJ8SOYB1PROD with NOTICES
buffer for MMFs would reduce their net
yields and possibly motivate
institutional investors to move assets
from MMFs to unregulated alternatives
(particularly if regulatory reform does
not include new constraints on such
vehicles). The effect of these competing
incentives on institutional investors’
cash management practices is uncertain,
but it is at least plausible that a
reorganization of MMFs as SPBs may
lead to a net shift of assets to
unregulated investment vehicles.
h. Enhanced Constraints on Unregulated
MMF Substitutes
New rules intended to reduce the
susceptibility of MMFs to runs generally
also will reduce the appeal of the funds
to many investors. For example, several
of the reforms recently adopted by the
SEC probably will reduce the net yields
that the funds pay to shareholders, and
a switch to floating NAVs would
eliminate a feature that some MMF
shareholders see as essential.
Reforms that reduce the appeal of
MMFs may motivate some institutional
investors to move assets to alternative
cash management vehicles with stable
NAVs, such as offshore MMFs,
enhanced cash funds, and other stable
value vehicles. These vehicles typically
invest in the same types of short-term
instruments that MMFs hold and share
many of the features that make MMFs
vulnerable to runs, so growth of
unregulated MMF substitutes would
likely increase systemic risks. However,
such funds need not comply with rule
2a–7 or other ICA protections and in
general are subject to little or no
regulatory oversight. In addition, the
risks posed by MMF substitutes are
difficult to monitor, since they provide
far less market transparency than
MMFs.
Thus, effective mitigation of systemic
risks may require policy reforms
targeted outside the MMF industry to
address risks posed by funds that
compete with MMFs and to combat
regulatory arbitrage that might offset
intended reductions in MMF risks. Such
reforms most likely would require
legislation and action by the SEC and
other agencies. For example,
consideration should be given to
prohibiting unregistered investment
vehicles from maintaining stable NAVs,
perhaps by amending sections 3(c)(1)
and 3(c)(7) of the ICA to specify that
exemptions from the requirement to
register as an investment company do
not apply to funds that seek a stable
NAV. Banking and state insurance
regulators might consider additional
restrictions to mitigate systemic risk for
bank common and collective funds and
VerDate Mar<15>2010
18:02 Nov 05, 2010
Jkt 223001
other investment pools that seek a stable
NAV but that are exempt from
registration under sections 3(c)(3) and
3(c)(11) of the ICA.
[FR Doc. 2010–28177 Filed 11–5–10; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 8011–01–P
SECURITIES AND EXCHANGE
COMMISSION
[Release No. 34–63223; File No. SR–FINRA–
2010–054]
Self-Regulatory Organizations;
Financial Industry Regulatory
Authority, Inc.; Notice of Filing and
Immediate Effectiveness of Proposed
Rule Change To Extend the
Operational Date of SR–FINRA–2009–
065
November 1, 2010.
Pursuant to Section 19(b)(1) of the
Securities Exchange Act of 1934
(‘‘Act’’) 1 and Rule 19b-4 thereunder,2
notice is hereby given that on October
27, 2010, the Financial Industry
Regulatory Authority, Inc. (‘‘FINRA’’)
filed with the Securities and Exchange
Commission (‘‘SEC’’ or ‘‘Commission’’)
the proposed rule change as described
in Items I and II, which Items have been
prepared by FINRA. FINRA has
designated the proposed rule change as
constituting a ‘‘non-controversial’’ rule
change under paragraph (f)(6) of Rule
19b-4 under the Act,3 which renders the
proposal effective upon receipt of this
filing by the Commission. The
Commission is publishing this notice to
solicit comments on the proposed rule
change from interested persons.
I. Self-Regulatory Organization’s
Statement of the Terms of Substance of
the Proposed Rule Change
FINRA is proposing to extend the
period during which FINRA may make
the rule changes set forth in SR–FINRA–
2009–065 and approved by the SEC on
February 22, 2010, effective to no later
than June 1, 2011.4
The proposed rule change would not
make any new changes to the text of
FINRA rules.
1 15
U.S.C. 78s(b)(1).
CFR 240.19b–4.
3 17 CFR 240.19b–4(f)(6).
4 See Securities Exchange Act Release No. 61566
(February 22, 2010), 75 FR 9262 (March 1, 2010)
(Order Approving File No. SR–FINRA–2009–065)
(hereinafter, ‘‘SEC Order Approving TRACE
Expansion—Asset-Backed Securities’’).
2 17
PO 00000
Frm 00059
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
II. Self-Regulatory Organization’s
Statement of the Purpose of, and
Statutory Basis for, the Proposed Rule
Change
In its filing with the Commission,
FINRA included statements concerning
the purpose of and basis for the
proposed rule change and discussed any
comments it received on the proposed
rule change. The text of these statements
may be examined at the places specified
in Item IV below. FINRA has prepared
summaries, set forth in sections A, B,
and C below, of the most significant
aspects of such statements.
A. Self-Regulatory Organization’s
Statement of the Purpose of, and
Statutory Basis for, the Proposed Rule
Change
1. Purpose
On October 1, 2009, FINRA filed SR–
FINRA–2009–065, a proposed rule
change to expand the Trade Reporting
and Compliance Engine (‘‘TRACE’’) to
designate asset-backed securities,
mortgage-backed securities and other
similar securities (collectively, ‘‘AssetBacked Securities’’) as eligible for
TRACE, and to establish reporting, fee
and other requirements for such
securities. In SR–FINRA–2009–065,
FINRA stated that it would announce
the effective date of the proposed rule
change in a Regulatory Notice to be
published ‘‘no later than 60 days
following Commission approval’’ and
the effective date would be ‘‘no later
than 270 days following publication’’ of
the Regulatory Notice announcing the
Commission’s approval.
The proposed rule change was
published for notice and comment.5
FINRA filed its response to comments
on December 22, 2009,6 and
Amendment No. 1 to SR–FINRA–2009–
065 on January 19, 2010 (hereinafter,
SR–FINRA–2009–065 and Amendment
No. 1 thereto are, together, the ‘‘TRACE
ABS filing’’).7 The Commission
5 See Securities Exchange Act Release No. 60860
(October 21, 2009), 74 FR 55600 (October 28, 2009)
(Notice of Filing of File No. SR–FINRA–2009–065).
6 See Letter from Sharon Zackula, Associate Vice
President and Associate General Counsel, FINRA, to
Elizabeth M. Murphy, Secretary, SEC, dated
December 22, 2009.
7 The TRACE ABS filing included amendments
to: (a) Rule 6710 to amend the defined terms,
‘‘Asset-Backed Security’’ and ‘‘TRACE-Eligible
Security’’ to include Asset-Backed Securities as
TRACE-Eligible Securities, to amend several other
defined terms, and to add several new defined
terms, most of which relate to Asset-Backed
Securities; (b) Rule 6730 to require the reporting of
Asset-Backed Securities transactions, to establish a
six-month pilot period for reporting such
transactions no later than T + 1 during TRACE
System hours, and to amend certain requirements
in connection with the reporting of commissions,
factors, transaction size and settlement terms in
E:\FR\FM\08NON1.SGM
08NON1
Agencies
[Federal Register Volume 75, Number 215 (Monday, November 8, 2010)]
[Notices]
[Pages 68636-68654]
From the Federal Register Online via the Government Printing Office [www.gpo.gov]
[FR Doc No: 2010-28177]
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
SECURITIES AND EXCHANGE COMMISSION
[Release No. IC-29497; File No. 4-619]
President's Working Group Report on Money Market Fund Reform
AGENCY: Securities and Exchange Commission.
ACTION: Request for comment.
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
SUMMARY: The Securities and Exchange Commission (``Commission'' or
``SEC'') is seeking comment on the options discussed in the report
presenting the results of the President's Working Group on Financial
Markets' study of possible money market fund reforms. Public comments
on the options discussed in this report will help inform consideration
of reform proposals addressing money market funds' susceptibility to
runs.
DATES: Comments should be received on or before January 10, 2011.
ADDRESSES: Comments may be submitted by any of the following methods:
Electronic Comments
Use the Commission's Internet comment form (https://www.sec.gov/rules/other.shtml); or
Send an e-mail to rule-comments@sec.gov. Please include
File Number 4-619 on the subject line; or
Use the Federal eRulemaking Portal (https://www.regulations.gov). Follow the instructions for submitting comments.
Paper Comments
Send paper comments in triplicate to Elizabeth M. Murphy,
Secretary, Securities and Exchange Commission, 100 F Street, NE.,
Washington, DC 20549-1090.
All submissions should refer to File Number 4-619. This file number
should
[[Page 68637]]
be included on the subject line if e-mail is used. To help us process
and review your comments more efficiently, please use only one method.
The Commission will post all comments on the Commission's Internet Web
site (https://www.sec.gov/rules/other.shtml). Comments are also
available for Web site viewing and printing in the Commission's Public
Reference Room, 100 F Street, NE., Washington, DC 20549, on official
business days between the hours of 10 am and 3 pm. All comments
received will be posted without change; we do not edit personal
identifying information from submissions. You should submit only
information that you wish to make available publicly.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: Daniele Marchesani or Sarah ten
Siethoff at (202) 551-6792, Division of Investment Management,
Securities and Exchange Commission, 100 F Street, NE., Washington, DC
20549-8549.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION:
I. The President's Working Group Report
Following the recommendation in the U.S. Department of the
Treasury's 2009 paper on Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation,
the President's Working Group on Financial Markets (``PWG'') conducted
a study of possible reforms that might mitigate money market funds'
susceptibility to runs.\1\ The results of this study are included in
the report issued on October 21, 2010 and attached to this release as
an Appendix (the ``Report'').\2\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1\ The members of the PWG include the Secretary of the Treasury
Department (as chairman of the PWG), the Chairman of the Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System, the Chairman of the SEC,
and the Chairman of the Commodity Futures Trading Commission.
\2\ The Report is also available at https://treas.gov/press/releases/docs/10.21%20PWG%20Report%20Final.pdf.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The Report expresses support for the new rules regulating money
market funds that the Commission approved last February.\3\ These new
rules seek to better protect money market fund investors in times of
financial market turmoil and lessen the possibility that money market
funds will not be able to withstand stresses similar to those
experienced in 2007 and 2008.\4\ When we adopted these rules, we
recognized that they were a first step to addressing regulatory
concerns as the events of 2007 and 2008 raised the question of whether
further, more fundamental changes to the regulatory structure governing
money market funds may be warranted.\5\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\3\ Money Market Fund Reform, Investment Company Act Release No.
29132 (Feb. 23, 2010) [75 FR 10060 (Mar. 4, 2010)] (``SEC Adopting
Release'').
\4\ The new rules further limit the credit, liquidity, and
interest rate risks money market funds may assume and require fund
managers to stress test their portfolios against potential economic
shocks. They also require money market funds to improve their
disclosure to investors and the Commission and provide a means to
wind down the operations of a fund that ``breaks the buck'' or
suffers a run, in an orderly way that is fair to the fund's
investors and reduces the risk of market losses that could spread to
other funds. For a discussion of the market stresses experienced by
money market funds in 2007 and 2008, see Money Market Fund Reform,
Investment Company Act Release No. 28807 (June 30, 2009) [74 FR
32688 (July 8, 2009)], at section II.D (``SEC Proposing Release'').
\5\ See SEC Adopting Release, supra note 3, at section I. In
proposing the new rules, we had requested comment on additional,
more fundamental regulatory changes, including several of those
discussed in the Report. See SEC Proposing Release, supra note 4, at
section III. Following the adoption of the new rules, the Commission
has continued to explore more significant changes in light of the
comments received on that release and through our staff's work
within the PWG.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The Report identifies the features that make money market funds
susceptible to runs as well as the systemic implications of the run on
prime money market funds that occurred in September 2008. The Report
states that the Commission's new rules alone could not be expected to
prevent a run of the type experienced in September 2008. Accordingly,
the Report outlines possible reforms that could supplement the new
rules we adopted and, individually or in combination, further reduce
money market funds' susceptibility to runs and the related systemic
risk. Some of the measures discussed in the Report could be implemented
by the Commission under our existing statutory authority; others would
require new legislation, coordination by multiple government agencies,
or the creation of new private entities.\6\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\6\ In particular, the Report notes that reforms may be needed
to avoid migration of institutional money market fund assets into
unregulated or less regulated money market investment vehicles.
Without new restrictions on such investment vehicles, money market
reform may motivate some investors to shift assets into money market
fund substitutes that may pose greater systemic risk than registered
money market funds. See section 3.h of the Report.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
II. Request for Comment
The Commission requests comment on the Report. Comments received
will better enable the Commission and the newly-established Financial
Stability Oversight Council (which will be taking over the work of the
PWG in this area) to consider the options discussed in this Report to
identify those most likely to materially reduce money market funds'
susceptibility to runs and to pursue their implementation. As the
Report states, we anticipate that following the comment period a series
of meetings will be held in Washington, DC with various stakeholders,
interested persons, experts, and regulators to discuss the options in
the Report.
We request comments on the options described in the Report both
individually and in combination. Commenters should address the
effectiveness of the options in mitigating systemic risks associated
with money market funds, as well as their potential impact on money
market fund investors, fund managers, issuers of short-term debt and
other stakeholders. We also are interested in comments on other issues
commenters believe are relevant to further money market fund reform,
including other approaches for lessening systemic risk not identified
in the Report. We urge commenters to submit empirical data and other
information in support of their comments.
Dated: November 3, 2010.
By the Commission.
Elizabeth M. Murphy,
Secretary.
BILLING CODE 8011-01-P
[[Page 68638]]
[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN08NO10.038
BILLING CODE 8011-01-C
[[Page 68639]]
Table of Contents
Executive Summary
1. Introduction and Background
a. Money Market Funds
b. MMFs' Susceptibility to Runs
c. MMFs in the Recent Financial Crisis
2. The SEC's Changes to the Regulation of MMFs
a. SEC Regulatory Changes
b. Need for Further Reform To Reduce Susceptibility to Runs
3. Policy Options for Further Reducing the Risks of Runs on MMFs
a. Floating Net Asset Values
b. Private Emergency Liquidity Facility for MMFs
c. Mandatory Redemptions in Kind
d. Insurance for MMFs
e. A Two-Tier System of MMFs, With Enhanced Protections for
Stable NAV MMFs
f. A Two-Tier System of MMFs, With Stable NAV MMFs Reserved for
Retail Investors
g. Regulating Stable NAV MMFs as Special Purpose Banks
h. Enhanced Constraints on Unregulated MMF Substitutes
Executive Summary
Several key events during the financial crisis underscored the
vulnerability of the financial system to systemic risk. One such event
was the September 2008 run on money market funds (MMFs), which began
after the failure of Lehman Brothers Holdings, Inc., caused significant
capital losses at a large MMF. Amid broad concerns about the safety of
MMFs and other financial institutions, investors rapidly redeemed MMF
shares, and the cash needs of MMFs exacerbated strains in short-term
funding markets. These strains, in turn, threatened the broader
economy, as firms and institutions dependent upon those markets for
short-term financing found credit increasingly difficult to obtain.
Forceful government action was taken to stop the run, restore investor
confidence, and prevent the development of an even more severe
recession. Even so, short-term funding markets remained disrupted for
some time.
The Treasury Department proposed in its Financial Regulatory
Reform: A New Foundation (2009), that the President's Working Group on
Financial Markets (PWG) prepare a report on fundamental changes needed
to address systemic risk and to reduce the susceptibility of MMFs to
runs. Treasury stated that the Securities and Exchange Commission's
(SEC) rule amendments to strengthen the regulation of MMFs--which were
in development at the time and which subsequently have been adopted--
should enhance investor protection and mitigate the risk of runs.
However, Treasury also noted that those rule changes could not, by
themselves, be expected to prevent a run on MMFs of the scale
experienced in September 2008. While suggesting a number of areas for
review, Treasury added that the PWG should consider ways to mitigate
possible adverse effects of further regulatory changes, such as the
potential flight of assets from MMFs to less regulated or unregulated
vehicles.
This report by the PWG responds to Treasury's call.\7\ The PWG
undertook a study of possible further reforms that, individually or in
combination, might mitigate systemic risk by complementing the SEC's
changes to MMF regulation. The PWG supports the SEC's recent actions
and agrees with the SEC that more should be done to address MMFs'
susceptibility to runs. This report details a number of options for
further reform that the PWG requests be examined by the newly
established Financial Stability Oversight Council (FSOC). These options
range from measures that could be implemented by the SEC under current
statutory authorities to broader changes that would require new
legislation, coordination by multiple government agencies, and the
creation of new private entities. For example, a new requirement that
MMFs adopt floating net asset values (NAVs) or that large funds meet
redemption requests in kind could be accomplished by SEC rule
amendments. In contrast, the introduction of a private emergency
liquidity facility, insurance for MMFs, conversion of MMFs to special
purpose banks, or a two-tier system of MMFs that might combine some of
the other measures likely would involve a coordinated effort by the
SEC, bank regulators, and financial firms.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\7\ The PWG (established by Executive Order 12631) is comprised
of the Secretary of the Treasury (who serves as its Chairman), the
Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board of Governors, the Chairman of
the Securities and Exchange Commission, and the Chairman of the
Commodity Futures Trading Commission.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Importantly, this report also emphasizes that the efficacy of the
options presented herein would be enhanced considerably by the
imposition of new constraints on less regulated or unregulated MMF
substitutes, such as offshore MMFs, enhanced cash funds, and other
stable value vehicles. Without new restrictions on such investment
vehicles, which would require legislation, new rules that further
constrain MMFs may motivate some investors to shift assets into MMF
substitutes that may pose greater systemic risk than MMFs.
The PWG requests that the FSOC consider the options discussed in
this report to identify those most likely to materially reduce MMFs'
susceptibility to runs and to pursue their implementation. To assist
the FSOC in any analysis, the SEC, as the regulator of MMFs, will
solicit public comments, including the production of empirical data and
other information in support of such comments. A notice and request for
comment will be published in the near future. Following a comment
period, a series of meetings will be held in Washington, DC with
various stakeholders, interested persons, experts, and regulators.
MMFs Are Susceptible to Runs
MMFs are mutual funds. They are investment vehicles that act as
intermediaries between shareholders who desire liquid investments and
borrowers who seek term funding. With nearly $3 trillion in assets
under management, MMFs are important providers of credit to businesses,
financial institutions, and governments. In addition, these funds are
significant investors in some short-term funding markets.
Like other mutual funds, MMFs are regulated under the Investment
Company Act of 1940 (ICA). In addition to ICA requirements for all
mutual funds, MMFs must comply with SEC rule 2a-7, which permits these
funds to maintain a stable net asset value (NAV) per share, typically
$1. However, if the mark-to-market per-share value of a fund's assets
falls more than one-half of 1 percent (to below $0.995), the fund must
reprice its shares, an event colloquially known as ``breaking the
buck.''
The events of September 2008 demonstrated that MMFs are susceptible
to runs. In addition, those events proved that runs on MMFs not only
harm fund shareholders, but may also cause severe dislocations in
short-term funding markets that curtail short-term financing for
companies and financial institutions and that ultimately result in a
decline in economic activity. Thus, reducing the susceptibility of MMFs
to runs and mitigating the effects of possible runs are important
components of the overall policy goals of decreasing and containing
systemic risks.
MMFs are vulnerable to runs because shareholders have an incentive
to redeem their shares before others do when there is a perception that
the fund might suffer a loss. Several features of MMFs, their sponsors,
and their investors contribute to this incentive. For example, although
a stable, rounded $1 NAV fosters an expectation of safety, MMFs are
subject to credit, interest-rate, and liquidity risks. Thus, when a
fund
[[Page 68640]]
incurs even a small loss because of those risks, the stable, rounded
NAV may subsidize shareholders who choose to redeem at the expense of
the remaining shareholders. A larger loss that causes a fund's share
price to drop below $1 per share (and thus break the buck) may prompt
more substantial sudden, destabilizing redemptions. Moreover, although
the expectations of safety fostered by the stable, rounded $1 NAV
suggest parallels to an insured demand deposit account, MMFs have no
formal capital buffers or insurance to prevent NAV declines; MMFs
instead have relied historically on discretionary sponsor capital
support to maintain stable NAVs. Accordingly, uncertainty about the
availability of such support during crises may contribute to runs.
Finally, because investors have come to view MMFs as extremely safe
vehicles that meet all withdrawal requests on demand (and that are, in
this sense, similar to banks), MMFs have attracted highly risk-averse
investors who are particularly prone to flight when they perceive the
possibility of a loss. These features likely mutually reinforce each
other in times of crisis.
The SEC's New Rules
In January 2010, the SEC adopted new rules for MMFs in order to
make these funds more resilient and less likely to break the buck. The
regulatory changes that mitigate systemic risks fall into three
principal categories. First, the new rules enhance risk-limiting
constraints on MMF portfolios by introducing new liquidity
requirements, imposing additional credit-quality standards, and
reducing the maximum allowable weighted average maturity of funds'
portfolios. Funds also are required to stress test their ability to
maintain a stable NAV. Second, the SEC's new rules permit a fund that
is breaking the buck to suspend redemptions promptly and liquidate its
portfolio in an orderly manner to limit contagion effects on other
funds. Third, the new rules place more stringent constraints on
repurchase agreements that are collateralized with private debt
instruments rather than government securities.
The Need for Further Measures
The SEC's new rules make MMFs more resilient and less risky and
therefore reduce the likelihood of runs on MMFs, increase the size of
runs that MMFs can withstand, and mitigate the systemic risks they
pose. However, the SEC's new rules address only some of the features
that make MMFs susceptible to runs, and more should be done to address
systemic risk and the structural vulnerabilities of MMFs to runs.
Indeed, the Chairman of the SEC characterized the new rules as ``a
first step'' in strengthening MMFs, and Treasury's Financial Regulatory
Reform: A New Foundation (2009) anticipated that measures taken by the
SEC ``should not, by themselves, be expected to prevent a run on MMFs
of the scale experienced in September 2008.''
Mitigating the risk of runs on MMFs is especially important because
the events of September 2008 may have created an expectation that, in a
future crisis, the government may provide support for MMFs at minimal
cost in order to minimize harm to MMF investors, short-term funding
markets, and the economy. Persistent expectations of unpriced
government support distort incentives in the MMF industry and pricing
in short-term funding markets, as well as heighten the systemic risk
posed by MMFs. It is thus essential that MMFs be required to
internalize fully the costs of liquidity or other risks associated with
their operation.
In formulating reforms for MMFs, policymakers should aim primarily
at mitigating systemic risk and containing the contagious effect that
strains at individual MMFs can have on other MMFs and on the broad
financial system. Importantly, preventing any individual MMF from ever
breaking the buck is not a practical policy objective--though the new
SEC rules for MMFs should help ensure that such events remain rare and
thus constitute a limited means of containing systemic risk.
Policy Options
The policy options discussed in this report may help further
mitigate the susceptibility of MMFs to runs. Some of these options may
be adopted by the SEC under its existing authorities. Others would
require legislation and action by multiple government agencies and the
MMF industry.
(a) Floating net asset values. A stable NAV has been a key element
of the appeal of MMFs to investors, but a stable, rounded NAV also
heightens funds' vulnerability to runs. Moving to a floating NAV would
help remove the perception that MMFs are risk-free and reduce
investors' incentives to redeem shares from distressed funds. However,
the elimination of the stable NAV for MMFs would be a dramatic change
for a nearly $3 trillion asset-management sector that has been built
around the stable share price. Such a change may have several
unintended consequences, including: (i) Reductions in MMFs' capacity to
provide short-term credit due to lower investor demand; (ii) a shift of
assets to less regulated or unregulated MMF substitutes such as
offshore MMFs, enhanced cash funds, and other stable value vehicles;
and (iii) unpredictable investor responses as MMF NAVs begin to
fluctuate more frequently.
(b) Private emergency liquidity facilities for MMFs. The liquidity
risk of MMFs contributes importantly to their vulnerability to runs,
and an external liquidity backstop to augment the SEC's new liquidity
requirements for MMFs would help mitigate this risk. Such a backstop
could buttress MMFs' ability to withstand outflows, internalize much of
the liquidity protection costs for the MMF industry, offer efficiency
gains from risk pooling, and reduce contagion effects. A liquidity
facility would preserve fund advisers' incentives for not taking
excessive risks because it would not protect funds from capital losses.
As such, a liquidity facility alone may not prevent broader runs on
MMFs triggered by concerns about widespread credit losses. Importantly,
significant capacity, structure, pricing, and operational hurdles would
have to be overcome to ensure that such a facility would be effective
during crises, that it would not unduly distort incentives, and that it
would not favor certain types of MMF business models.
(c) Mandatory redemptions in kind. When investors make large
redemptions from MMFs, they may impose liquidity costs on other
shareholders in the fund by forcing MMFs to sell assets in an untimely
manner. A requirement that MMFs distribute large redemptions in kind,
rather than in cash, would force these redeeming shareholders to bear
their own liquidity costs and thus reduce the incentive to redeem.
Depending on whether redeeming shareholders immediately sell the
securities received, redemptions in kind may still generate market
effects. Moreover, mandating redemptions in kind could present some
operational and policy challenges. The SEC, for example, would have to
make key judgments regarding when a fund must redeem in kind and how
funds would fairly distribute portfolio securities.
(d) Insurance for MMFs. Treasury's Temporary Guarantee Program for
Money Market Funds helped slow the run on MMFs in September 2008, and
some form of insurance for MMF shareholders might be helpful in
mitigating the risk of runs in MMFs. Unlike a private liquidity
facility, insurance would limit credit losses to shareholders, so
appropriate risk-based pricing would be critical in preventing
insurance from distorting incentives,
[[Page 68641]]
but such pricing might be difficult to achieve in practice. The
appropriate scope of coverage also presents a challenge; unlimited
coverage would likely cause large shifts of assets from the banking
sector to MMFs, but limited insurance might do little to reduce
institutional investors' incentives to run from distressed MMFs. The
optimal form for insurance--whether it would be private, public, or a
mix of the two--is also uncertain, particularly given the recent
experience with private financial guarantees.
(e) A two-tier system of MMFs with enhanced protection for stable
NAV funds. Reforms aimed at reducing MMFs' susceptibility to runs may
be particularly effective if they permit investors to select the types
of MMFs that best balance their appetite for risk and their preference
for yield. Policymakers could allow two types of MMFs: Stable NAV
funds, which would be subject to enhanced protections such as, for
example, required participation in a private liquidity facility or
enhanced regulatory requirements; and floating NAV funds, which would
have to comply with certain, but not all, rule 2a-7 restrictions (and
which would presumably offer higher yields). Because this two-tier
system would permit stable NAV funds to continue to be available, it
would reduce the likelihood of a substantial decline in demand for MMFs
and large-scale shifts of assets toward unregulated vehicles. At the
same time, the forms of protection encompassed by such a system would
mitigate the risks associated with stable NAV funds. It would also
avoid problems that might be encountered in transitioning the entire
MMF industry to a floating NAV. Moreover, during a crisis, a two-tier
system might prevent large shifts of assets out of MMFs--and a
reduction in credit supplied by the funds--if investors simply shift
assets from riskier floating NAV funds toward safer (because of the
enhanced protections) stable NAV funds. However, implementation of such
a two-tier system would present the same challenges as the introduction
of any individual enhanced protections (such as mandated access to a
private emergency liquidity facility) that would be required for stable
NAV funds, and the effectiveness of a two-tier system would depend on
investors' understanding the risks associated with each type of fund.
(f) A two-tier system of MMFs with stable NAV MMFs reserved for
retail investors. Another approach to the two-tier system already
described could distinguish funds by investor type: Stable NAV MMFs
could be made available only to retail investors, who could choose
between stable NAV and floating NAV funds, while institutional
investors would be restricted to floating NAV funds. The run on MMFs in
September 2008 was almost exclusively due to redemptions from prime
MMFs by institutional investors. Such investors typically have
generated greater cash-flow volatility for MMFs than retail investors
and have been much quicker to redeem MMF shares from stable NAV funds
opportunistically. Hence, this approach would mitigate risks associated
with a stable NAV by addressing the investor base of stable NAV funds
rather than by mandating other types of enhanced protections for those
funds. Such a system also would protect the interests of retail
investors by reducing the likelihood that a run might begin in
institutional MMFs (as it did in September 2008) and spread to retail
funds, while preserving the original purpose of MMFs, which was to
provide retail investors with cost-effective, diversified investments
in money market instruments. This approach would require the SEC to
define who would qualify as retail and institutional investors, and
distinguishing those categories will present challenges. In addition, a
prohibition on sales of stable NAV MMFs shares to institutional
investors may have several of the same unintended consequences as a
requirement that all MMFs adopt floating NAVs (see option (a) in this
section).
(g) Regulating stable NAV MMFs as special purpose banks. Functional
similarities between MMF shares and bank deposits, as well as the risk
of runs on both, provide a rationale for requiring stable NAV MMFs to
reorganize as special purpose banks (SPBs) subject to banking oversight
and regulation. As banks, MMFs could have access to government
insurance and lender-of-last-resort facilities. An advantage of such a
reorganization could be that it uses a well-understood regulatory
framework for the mitigation of systemic risk. But while the conceptual
basis for this option is fairly straightforward, its implementation
might take a broad range of forms and would probably require
legislation together with interagency coordination. An important hurdle
for successful conversion of MMFs to SPBs may be the very large amounts
of equity necessary to capitalize the new banks. In addition, to the
extent that deposits in the new SPBs would be insured, the potential
government liabilities through deposit insurance would be increased
substantially, and the development of an appropriate pricing scheme for
such insurance would present some of the same challenges as the pricing
of deposit insurance. More broadly, the possible interactions between
the new SPBs and the existing banking system would have to be studied
carefully by policymakers.
(h) Enhanced constraints on unregulated MMF substitutes. New
measures intended to mitigate MMF risks may also reduce the appeal of
MMFs to many investors. While it is likely that some (particularly
retail) investors may move their assets from MMFs to bank deposits if
regulation of MMFs becomes too burdensome and meaningfully reduces MMF
returns, others may be motivated to shift assets to unregulated funds
with stable NAVs, such as offshore MMFs, enhanced cash funds, and other
stable value vehicles. Such funds, which typically hold assets similar
to those held by MMFs, are vulnerable to runs but are less transparent
and less constrained than MMFs, so their growth would likely pose
systemic risks. Hence, effective mitigation of this risk may require
policy reforms targeting regulatory arbitrage. Reforms of this type
generally would require legislation and action by the SEC and other
agencies.
1. Introduction and Background
a. Money Market Funds
MMFs are mutual funds that offer individuals, businesses, and
governments a convenient and cost-effective means of pooled investing
in money market instruments. MMFs provide an economically important
service by acting as intermediaries between shareholders who desire
liquid investments, often for cash management, and borrowers who seek
term funding.
With nearly $3 trillion in assets under management, MMFs are
important providers of credit to businesses, financial institutions,
and governments. Indeed, these funds play a dominant role in some
short-term credit markets. For example, MMFs own almost 40 percent of
outstanding commercial paper, roughly two-thirds of short-term state
and local government debt, and significant portions of outstanding
short-term Treasury and federal agency securities.
Like other mutual funds, MMFs are regulated under the Investment
Company Act of 1940 (ICA). In addition to the requirements applicable
to other funds under the ICA, MMFs must comply with rule 2a-7, which
permits these funds to maintain a ``stable'' net
[[Page 68642]]
asset value (NAV) per share, typically $1, through the use of the
``amortized cost'' method of valuation. Under this method, securities
are valued at acquisition cost, with adjustments for amortization of
premium or accretion of discount, instead of at fair market value. To
prevent substantial deviations between the $1 share price and the mark-
to-market per-share value of the fund's assets (its ``shadow NAV''), a
MMF must periodically compare the two. If there is a difference of more
than one-half of 1 percent (or $0.005 per share), the fund must re-
price its shares, an event colloquially known as ``breaking the buck.''
Historically, the stable NAV has played an important role in
distinguishing MMFs from other mutual funds and in facilitating the use
of MMFs as cash management vehicles. Rule 2a-7 also imposes credit-
quality, maturity, and diversification requirements on MMF portfolios
designed to ensure that the funds' investing remains consistent with
the objective of maintaining a stable NAV. A MMF's $1 share price is
not guaranteed through any form of deposit or other insurance, or
otherwise--indeed, MMF prospectuses must state that shares can lose
value. However, by permitting amortized cost valuation, rule 2a-7
affords MMFs price stability under normal market conditions.
MMFs pursue a range of investment objectives, with corresponding
differences in portfolio composition. For example, tax-exempt MMFs
purchase short-term municipal securities and offer tax-exempt income to
fund shareholders, while Treasury-only MMFs hold only obligations of
the U.S. Treasury. In contrast, prime MMFs invest largely in private
debt instruments, such as commercial paper and certificates of deposit,
and, commensurate with the greater risks in prime MMF portfolios, they
generally pay higher yields than Treasury-only funds.
MMFs are marketed both to retail investors (that is, individuals),
for whom MMFs are the only means of investing in many money market
instruments, and to institutions, which are often attracted by the
convenience and cost efficiency of MMFs, even though many institutional
investors have the ability to invest directly in the instruments held
by MMFs. Institutional MMFs, which currently account for about two-
thirds of the assets under management in MMFs, have grown much faster,
on net, in the past two decades than retail funds. The rapid growth of
institutional funds has important implications for the MMF industry,
because institutional funds tend to have more volatile flows and more
yield-sensitive shareholders than retail funds.
MMFs compete with other stable-value, low-risk investments. Because
MMFs generally maintain stable NAVs, offer redemptions on demand, and
often provide services that compete with those offered to holders of
insured deposits (such as transactions services), many retail customers
likely consider MMF shares and bank deposits as near substitutes, even
if the two classes of products are fundamentally different (most
notably because MMF shares are not insured and because MMFs and banks
are subject to very different regulatory regimes). Some institutional
investors may also view bank deposits and MMFs as near substitutes,
although usual limitations on deposit insurance coverage and interest
payments on deposits likely reduce the attractiveness of bank deposits
for most such investors.\8\ Institutional investors also have access to
less-regulated MMF substitutes (for example, offshore MMFs, enhanced
cash funds, and other stable value vehicles) and may perceive them as
near substitutes for MMFs, even if those vehicles are not subject to
the protections afforded by rule 2a-7.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\8\ Under the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation's (FDIC)
Temporary Liquidity Guarantee Program, coverage limits on
noninterest-bearing transaction deposits in FDIC-insured
institutions were temporarily lifted beginning in October 2008 and
coverage will extend through 2010. Effective December 31, 2010,
pursuant to the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer
Protection Act, Public Law 111-203, (``Dodd-Frank Act''), all
noninterest-bearing transaction deposits will have unlimited
coverage until January 1, 2013. In addition, section 627 of the
Dodd-Frank Act repeals the prohibition on banks paying interest on
corporate demand deposit accounts effective July 21, 2011.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
b. MMFs' Susceptibility to Runs
In the twenty-seven years since the adoption of rule 2a-7, only two
MMFs have broken the buck. In 1994, a small MMF suffered a capital loss
because of exposures to interest rate derivatives, but the event passed
without significant repercussions. In contrast, as further discussed
later, when the Reserve Primary Fund broke the buck in September 2008,
it helped ignite a massive run on prime MMFs that contributed to severe
dislocations in short-term credit markets and strains on the businesses
and institutions that obtain funding in those markets.\9\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\9\ Section 1(c) contains more detail on the MMF industry's
experience during the recent financial crisis.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Although the run on MMFs in 2008 is itself unique in the history of
the industry, the events of 2008 underscored the susceptibility of MMFs
to runs. That susceptibility arises because, when shareholders perceive
a risk that a fund will suffer losses, each shareholder has an
incentive to redeem shares before other shareholders. Five features of
MMFs, their sponsors, and their investors principally contribute to
this incentive:
(i) Maturity transformation with limited liquidity resources. One
important economic function of MMFs is their role as intermediaries
between shareholders who want liquid investments and borrowers who
desire term funding. As such, MMFs offer shares that are payable on
demand, but they invest both in cash-like instruments and in short-term
securities that are less liquid, including, for example, term
commercial paper. Redemptions in excess of MMFs' cash-like liquidity
may force funds to sell less liquid assets. When money markets are
strained, funds may not be able to obtain full value (that is,
amortized cost) for such assets in secondary markets and may incur
losses as a consequence. Investors thus have an incentive to redeem
shares before a fund has depleted its cash-like instruments (which
serve as its liquidity buffer).
(ii) NAVs rounded to $1. Share prices of MMFs are rounded to the
nearest cent, typically resulting in a $1 NAV per share. The rounding
fosters an expectation that MMF share prices will not fluctuate, which
exacerbates investors' incentive to run when there is risk that prices
will fluctuate. When a MMF that has experienced a small (less than one-
half of 1 percent) capital loss redeems shares at the full $1 NAV, it
concentrates the loss among the remaining shareholders. Thus,
redemptions from such a fund further depress the market value of its
assets per share outstanding (its shadow NAV), and redemptions of
sufficient scale may cause the fund to break the buck. Early redeemers
are therefore more likely to receive the usual $1 NAV than those who
wait.
(iii) Portfolios exposed to credit and interest rate risks. MMFs
invest in securities with credit and interest-rate risks. Although
these risks are generally small given the short maturity of the
securities and the high degree of portfolio diversification, even a
small capital loss, in combination with other features of MMFs, can
trigger a significant volume of redemptions. The events of September
2008--when losses on Lehman Brothers Holdings, Inc. (Lehman Brothers)
debt instruments caused just one MMF to break the buck and triggered a
broad run on MMFs--highlight the fact that credit losses at
[[Page 68643]]
even a single fund may have serious implications for the whole industry
and consequently for the entire financial system.\10\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\10\ Souring credits and rapid increases in interest rates have
adversely affected MMFs on other occasions. For example, beginning
in the summer of 2007, MMF exposures to structured investment
vehicles and other asset-backed commercial paper caused capital
losses at many MMFs, and many MMF sponsors voluntarily provided
capital support that prevented some funds from breaking the buck.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
(iv) Discretionary sponsor capital support. MMFs invest in assets
that may lose value, but the funds have no formal capital buffers or
insurance to maintain their $1 share prices in the event of a loss on a
portfolio asset.
The MMF industry's record of maintaining a stable NAV reflects, in
part, substantial discretionary intervention by MMF sponsors (that is,
fund advisers, their affiliates, and their parent firms) to support
funds that otherwise might have broken the buck.\11\ Sponsors do not
commit to support an MMF in advance, because an explicit commitment may
require the sponsor to consolidate the fund on its balance sheet and--
if the sponsor is subject to regulatory capital requirements--hold
additional regulatory capital against the contingent exposure. Nor is
there any requirement that sponsors support ailing MMFs; such a mandate
would transform the nature of MMF shares by shifting risks from
investors to sponsors and probably would require government supervision
and monitoring of sponsors' resources and capital adequacy.\12\
Instead, sponsor capital support remains expressly voluntary, and not
all MMFs have a sponsor capable of fully supporting its MMFs.
Nonetheless, a long history of such support probably has contributed
substantially to the perceived safety of MMFs.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\11\ For example, more than 100 MMFs received sponsor capital
support in 2007 and 2008 because of investments in securities that
lost value and because of the run on MMFs in September and October
2008. See Securities and Exchange Commission (2009) ``Money Market
Reform: Proposed Rule,'' pp. 13-14, 17, and notes 38 and 54.
\12\ Even discretionary support for MMFs may lead to concerns
about the safety and soundness of MMF sponsors. Sponsors that foster
expectations of such support may be granting a form of implicit
recourse that is not reflected on sponsors' balance sheets or in
their regulatory capital ratios, and such implicit recourse may
contribute to broader systemic risk.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
However, the possibility that sponsors may become unwilling or
unable to provide expected support during a crisis is itself a source
of systemic risk. Indeed, sponsor support is probably least reliable
when systemic risks are most salient.\13\ Moreover, MMFs without deep-
pocketed sponsors remain vulnerable to runs that can affect the entire
industry. The Reserve Primary Fund was not the only MMF that held
Lehman Brothers debt at the time of the Lehman Brothers' bankruptcy in
September 2008, but it broke the buck because the Reserve Primary Fund,
unlike some of its competitors, had substantial holdings of Lehman
Brothers debt and Reserve did not have the resources to support its
fund. Investors also recognized the riskiness of sponsor support more
broadly during the run on MMFs in 2008. For example, outflows from
prime MMFs following the Lehman Brothers bankruptcy tended to be larger
among MMFs with sponsors that were themselves under strain (as measured
by credit default swap spreads for parent firms or affiliates),
indicating that MMF investors quickly redeemed shares on concerns about
sponsors' potential inabilities to bolster ailing funds.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\13\ Other forms of discretionary financial support, such as
that provided by dealers for auction rate securities, did not fare
well during the financial crisis.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
(v) Investors' low risk tolerance and expectations. Investors have
come to view MMF shares as extremely safe, in part because of the
funds' stable NAVs and sponsors' record of supporting funds that might
otherwise lose value. MMFs' history of maintaining stable value has
attracted highly risk-averse investors who are prone to withdraw assets
rapidly when losses appear possible.
MMFs, like other mutual funds, commit to redeem shares based on the
fund's NAV at the time of redemption. MMFs are under no legal or
regulatory requirement to redeem shares at $1; rule 2a-7 only requires
that MMFs be managed to maintain a stable NAV. Yet sponsor-supported
stable, rounded NAVs and the typical $1 MMF share price foster
investors' impressions that MMFs are extremely safe investments.
Indeed, the growth of retail MMFs in recent decades may have reflected
some substitution from insured deposits at commercial banks, thrifts,
and credit unions, particularly as MMFs have offered transactions
services and other bank-like functions. Although MMF shares, unlike
bank deposits, are not government insured and are not backed by capital
to absorb losses, this distinction may have become even less clear to
retail investors following the unprecedented government support of MMFs
in 2008 and 2009. Furthermore, that recent support may have left even
sophisticated institutional investors with the mistaken impression that
MMF safety is enhanced because the government stands ready to support
the industry again with the same tools employed at the height of the
financial crisis.
The growth of institutional MMFs in recent years probably has
heightened both the risk aversion of the typical MMF shareholder and
the volatility of MMF cash flows. Many institutional investors cannot
tolerate fluctuations in share prices for a variety of reasons. In
addition, institutional investors are typically more sophisticated than
retail investors in obtaining and analyzing information about MMF
portfolios and risks, have larger amounts at stake, and hence are
quicker to respond to events that may threaten the stable NAV. In fact,
institutional MMFs have historically experienced much more volatile
flows than retail funds. During the run on MMFs in September 2008,
institutional funds accounted for more than 90 percent of the net
redemptions from prime MMFs.
The interaction of these five features is critical. Taken alone,
each of the features just listed probably would only modestly increase
the vulnerability of MMFs to runs, but, in combination, the features
tend to amplify and reinforce one another. For example, equity mutual
funds perform maturity transformation and take on capital risks, but
even after large capital losses, outflows from equity funds tend to be
small relative to assets, most likely because equity funds are not
marketed for their ability to maintain stable NAVs, do not attract the
risk-averse investor base that characterizes MMFs, and offer the
opportunity for capital appreciation. If MMFs with rounded NAVs had
lacked sponsor support over the past few decades, many might have
broken the buck and diminished the expectation of a stable $1 share
price. In that case, investors who nonetheless elected to hold shares
in such funds might have become more tolerant of risk and less inclined
to run. If MMFs had attracted primarily a retail investor base rather
than an institutional base, investors might be slower to respond to
strains on a MMF. And even a highly risk-averse investor base would not
necessarily make MMFs susceptible to runs--and to contagion arising
from runs on other MMFs--if funds had a credible means to guarantee
their $1 NAVs. Thus, policy responses that diminish the reinforcing
interactions among the features discussed herein hold promise for
muting overall risks posed by MMFs.
c. MMFs in the Recent Financial Crisis
The turmoil in financial markets in 2007 and 2008 caused severe
strains both among MMFs and in the short-term debt markets in which
MMFs invest. Beginning in mid-2007, dozens of funds faced losses from
holdings of highly
[[Page 68644]]
rated asset-backed commercial paper (ABCP) issued by structured
investment vehicles (SIVs), some of which had exposures to the subprime
mortgage market. Fear of such losses at one MMF caused that fund to
experience a substantial run in August 2007, which was brought under
control when the fund's sponsor purchased more than $5 billion of
illiquid securities from the fund. Indeed, financial support from MMF
sponsors in recent years probably prevented a number of funds from
breaking the buck because of losses on SIV paper.
The crisis for MMFs worsened considerably in September 2008 with
the bankruptcy of Lehman Brothers on September 15 and mounting concerns
about other issuers of commercial paper, particularly financial firms.
The Reserve Primary Fund, a $62 billion MMF, held $785 million in
Lehman Brothers debt on the day of Lehman Brothers' bankruptcy and
immediately began experiencing a run--shareholders requested
redemptions of approximately $40 billion in just two days. In order to
meet the redemptions, the Reserve Primary Fund depleted its cash
reserves and began seeking to sell its portfolio securities, which
further depressed their valuations. Unlike other MMFs that held
distressed securities, the Reserve Primary Fund had no affiliate with
sufficient resources to support its $1 NAV, and Reserve announced on
September 16 that its Primary Fund would break the buck and re-price
its shares at $0.97. On September 22, the SEC issued an order
permitting the suspension of redemptions in certain Reserve MMFs to
permit their orderly liquidation.
The run quickly spread to other prime MMFs, which held sizable
amounts of financial sector debt that investors feared might decline
rapidly in value. During the week of September 15, 2008, investors
withdrew approximately $310 billion (15 percent of assets) from prime
MMFs, with the heaviest redemptions coming from institutional funds. To
meet these redemption requests, MMFs depleted their cash positions and
sought to sell portfolio securities into already illiquid markets.
These efforts caused further declines in the prices of short-term
instruments and put pressure on per-share values of fund portfolios,
threatening MMFs' stable NAVs. Nonetheless, only one MMF--the Reserve
Primary Fund--broke the buck, because many MMF sponsors provided
substantial financial support to prevent capital losses in their funds.
Fearing further redemptions, many MMF advisers limited new
portfolio investments to cash, U.S. Treasury securities, and overnight
instruments, and avoided term commercial paper, certificates of
deposit, and other short-term credit instruments. During September
2008, MMFs reduced their holdings of commercial paper by about $170
billion (25 percent). As market participants hoarded cash and refused
to lend to one another on more than an overnight basis, interest rates
spiked and short-term credit markets froze. Commercial paper issuers
were required to make significant draws on their backup lines of
credit, placing additional pressure on the balance sheets of commercial
banks.
On September 19, 2008, Treasury and the Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System (Federal Reserve) announced two unprecedented
market interventions to stabilize MMFs and to provide liquidity to
short-term funding markets. Treasury's Temporary Guarantee Program for
Money Market Funds temporarily provided guarantees for shareholders in
MMFs that elected to participate in the program.\14\ The Federal
Reserve's Asset-Backed Commercial Paper Money Market Mutual Fund
Liquidity Facility (AMLF) extended credit to U.S. banks and bank
holding companies to finance their purchases of high-quality ABCP from
MMFs.\15\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\14\ MMFs that elected to participate in the program paid fees
of 4 to 6 basis points at an annual rate for the guarantee. The
Temporary Guarantee Program for Money Market Funds expired on
September 18, 2009.
\15\ The AMLF expired on February 1, 2010.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The announcements of these government programs substantially slowed
the run on prime MMFs. Outflows from prime MMFs diminished to about $65
billion in the week after the announcements and, by mid-October, these
MMFs began attracting net inflows. Moreover, in the weeks following the
government interventions, markets for commercial paper and other short-
term debt instruments stabilized considerably.\16\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\16\ Several other unprecedented government interventions that
provided additional support for the MMF industry and for short-term
funding markets were introduced after the run on MMFs had largely
abated. For example, the Federal Reserve in October 2008 established
the Commercial Paper Funding Facility (CPFF), which provided loans
for purchases (through a special purpose vehicle) of term commercial
paper from issuers. The CPFF, which expired on February 1, 2010,
helped issuers repay investors--such as MMFs--who held maturing
paper. Also in October 2008, the Federal Reserve announced the Money
Market Investor Funding Facility (MMIFF), which was intended to
bolster liquidity for MMFs by financing (through special purpose
vehicles) purchases of securities from the funds. The MMIFF was
never used and expired on October 30, 2009. In November 2008,
Treasury agreed to become a buyer of last resort for certain
securities held by the Reserve U.S. Government Fund (a MMF), in
order to facilitate an orderly and timely liquidation of the fund.
Under the agreement, Treasury would purchase certain securities
issued by government sponsored enterprises at amortized cost (not
mark to market), and $3.6 billion of such purchases were completed
in January 2009.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
2. The SEC's Changes to the Regulation of MMFs
The effects of the financial turmoil in 2007 and 2008 on MMFs--and,
in particular, the run on these funds in September 2008 and its
consequences--have highlighted the need for reforms to mitigate the
systemic risks posed by MMFs. Appropriate reforms include changes to
MMF regulations as well as broader policy actions. This section first
examines rule changes that have been adopted by the SEC to improve the
safety and resilience of MMFs and then discusses some limitations in
these measures' mitigation of systemic risk and the need for further
reforms.
Notwithstanding the need for reform, the significance of MMFs in
the U.S. financial system suggests that changes must be considered
carefully. Tighter restrictions on MMFs might, for example, lead to a
reduction in the supply of short-term credit, a shift in assets to
substitute investment vehicles that are subject to less regulation than
MMFs, and significant impairment of an important cash-management tool
for investors. Moreover, the economic importance of risk-taking by
MMFs--as lenders in private debt markets and as investments that appeal
to shareholders' preferences for risk and return--suggests that the
appropriate objective for reform should not be to eliminate all risks
posed by MMFs. Attempting to prevent any fund from ever breaking the
buck would be an impractical goal that might lead, for example, to
draconian and--from a broad economic perspective--counterproductive
measures, such as outright prohibitions on purchases of private debt
instruments and securities with maturities of more than one day.
Instead, policymakers should balance the benefits of allowing
individual MMFs to take some risks and facilitating private and public
borrowers' access to term financing in money markets with the broader
objective of mitigating systemic risks--in particular, the risk that
one fund's problems may cause serious harm to other MMFs, their
shareholders, short-term funding markets, the financial system, and the
economy.
a. SEC Regulatory Changes
In January 2010, the SEC adopted new rules regulating MMFs in order
to make these funds more resilient to market
[[Page 68645]]
disruptions and thus less likely to break the buck. The new rules also
might help reduce the likelihood of runs on MMFs by facilitating the
orderly liquidation of funds that have broken the buck. The SEC
designed the new rules primarily to meet its statutory obligations
under the ICA to protect investors and promote capital formation.
Nonetheless, the rules should mitigate (although not eliminate)
systemic risks by reducing the susceptibility of MMFs to runs, both by
lessening the likelihood that an individual fund will break the buck
and by containing the damage should one break the buck. The rule
changes fall into three principal categories.
(i) Enhanced Risk-Limiting Constraints on Money Market Fund
Portfolios. Each of the changes that follow further constrains risk-
taking by MMFs.
Liquidity Risk. One of the most important SEC rule changes aimed at
reducing systemic risk associated with MMFs is a requirement that each
fund maintain a substantial liquidity cushion. Augmented liquidity
should position MMFs to better withstand heavy redemptions without
selling portfolio securities into potentially distressed markets at
discounted prices. Forced ``fire sales'' to meet heavy redemptions may
cause losses not only for the fund that must sell the securities, but
also for other MMFs that hold the same or similar securities. Thus, a
substantial liquidity cushion should help reduce the risk that strains
on one MMF will be transmitted to other funds and to short-term credit
markets.
Specifically, the SEC's new rules require that MMFs maintain
minimum daily and weekly liquidity positions. Daily liquidity, which
must be at least 10 percent of a MMF's assets, includes cash, U.S.
Treasury obligations, and securities (including repurchase agreements)
that mature or for which the fund has a contractual right to obtain
cash within a day. Weekly liquidity, which must be at least 30 percent
of each MMF's assets, includes cash, securities that mature or can be
converted to cash within a week, U.S. Treasury obligations, and
securities issued by federal government agencies and government-
sponsored enterprises with remaining maturities of 60 days or less.\17\
Furthermore, the new rules require MMF advisers to maintain larger
liquidity buffers as necessary to meet reasonably foreseeable
redemptions.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\17\ Tax-exempt money market funds are exempt from daily minimum
liquidity requirements but not the weekly minimum liquidity
requirements, because most tax-exempt fund portfolios consist of
longer-term floating- and variable-rate securities with seven-day
``put'' options that effectively give the funds weekly liquidity.
Tax-exempt funds are unlikely to have investment alternatives that
would permit them to meet a daily liquidity requirement.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Credit Risk. The new rules reduce MMFs' maximum allowable holdings
of ``second-tier'' securities, which carry more credit risk than first-
tier securities, to no more than 3 percent of each fund's assets.\18\
In addition, a MMF's exposure to a single second-tier issuer is now
limited to one-half of 1 percent of the fund's assets, and funds can
only purchase second-tier securities with maturities of 45 days or
less. These new constraints reduce the likelihood that individual funds
will be exposed to a credit event that could cause the funds to break
the buck. Also, since second-tier securities often trade in thinner
markets, these changes should improve the ability of individual MMFs to
maintain a stable NAV during periods of market volatility.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\18\ Under SEC rule 2a-7, for short-term debt securities to
qualify as second-tier securities, they generally must have received
the second highest short-term debt rating from the credit rating
agencies or be of comparable quality. Section 939A of the Dodd-Frank
Act requires that government agencies remove references to credit
ratings in their rules and replace them with other credit standards
that the agency determines appropriate. As a result, the SEC will be
reconsidering this rule and its provisions relating to second-tier
securities to comply with this statutory mandate.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Interest Rate Risk. By reducing the maximum allowable weighted
average maturity (WAM) of fund portfolios from 90 days to 60 days, the
new rules are intended to diminish funds' exposure to interest rate
risk and increase the liquidity of fund portfolios. The SEC also
introduced a new weighted average life (WAL) measure for MMFs--and set
a ceiling for WAL at 120 days--in order to lower funds' exposure to
interest-rate, credit, and liquidity risks associated with the
floating-rate obligations that MMFs commonly hold.\19\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\19\ For purposes of computing WAM, a floating-rate security's
``maturity'' can be its next interest-rate reset date. In computing
WAL, the life of a security is determined solely by its final
maturity date. Hence, WAL should be more useful than WAM in
reflecting the risks of widening spreads on longer-term floating-
rate securities.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Stress Testing. Finally, the SEC's new rules require fund advisers
to periodically stress test their funds' ability to maintain a stable
NAV per share based on certain hypothetical events, including a change
in short-term interest rates, an increase in shareholder redemptions, a
downgrade or default of a portfolio security, and a change in interest
rate spreads. Regular and methodical monitoring of these risks and
their potential effects should help funds weather stress without
incident.
(ii) Facilitating Orderly Fund Liquidations. The new SEC rules
should reduce the systemic risk posed by MMFs by permitting a fund that
is breaking the buck to promptly suspend redemptions and liquidate its
portfolio in an orderly manner. This new rule should help prevent a
capital loss at one fund from forcing a disorderly sale of portfolio
securities that might disrupt short-term markets and diminish share
values of other MMFs. Moreover, the ability of a fund to suspend
redemptions should help prevent investors who redeem shares from
benefiting at the expense of those who remain invested in a fund.
(iii) Repurchase Agreements. The SEC's new rules place more
stringent constraints on repurchase agreements that are collateralized
with private debt instruments rather than cash equivalents or
government securities. MMFs are among the largest purchasers of
repurchase agreements, which they use to invest cash, typically on an
overnight basis. Because the collateral usually consists of long-term
debt securities, a MMF cannot hold the securities underlying this
collateral without violating SEC rules that limit MMF holdings to
short-term obligations. Accordingly, if a significant counterparty
fails to repurchase securities as stipulated in a repurchase agreement,
its MMF counterparties can be expected to direct custodians to sell the
collateral immediately, and sales of private debt instruments could be
sizable and disruptive to financial markets. To address this risk, the
SEC's new rule places additional constraints on MMFs' exposure to
counterparties through repurchase agreement transactions that are
collateralized by securities other than cash equivalents or government
securities.
b. Need for Further Reform To Reduce Susceptibility to Runs
The new SEC rules make MMFs more resilient and less risky and
therefore reduce the likelihood of runs on funds, increase the size of
runs that they could withstand, and mitigate the systemic risks they
pose. However, more can be done to address the structural
vulnerabilities of MMFs to runs. Indeed, the Chairman of the SEC
characterized its new rules as ``a first step'' in strengthening MMFs
and noted that a number of additional possible reforms (many of which
are presented in section 3 of this report) are under discussion.
Likewise, Treasury's Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
(2009) anticipated that measures taken by the SEC ``should not, by
themselves, be expected to prevent a run on MMFs of the scale
experienced in September 2008.''
[[Page 68646]]
Of the five features that make MMFs vulnerab