Self-Regulatory Organizations; NYSE Arca, Inc.; Order Setting Aside Action by Delegated Authority and Approving Proposed Rule Change Relating to NYSE Arca Data, 74770-74797 [E8-28908]
Download as PDF
74770
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 237 / Tuesday, December 9, 2008 / Notices
convicted of any of the crimes listed in
the rule.
(iii) An applicant, member, or its
controlling management being
permanently or temporarily enjoined
from acting on behalf of a financial
institution such as a broker-dealer.
(iv) An applicant or member’s
suspension or termination from
participation in a national securities
association, exchange registered under
the Exchange Act, a self-regulatory
organization, clearing agency, or
securities depository.
Pursuant to the proposed change,
NSCC will continue to be able to cease
to act for a member when any of the
factors in sections (i) through (iv) above
are present. Addendum S will be struck
entirely from the rules, and the listed
disqualification criteria will be included
in NSCC’s proposed Rule 2A ‘‘Initial
Membership Requirements.’’ 4
III. Discussion
Section 19(b) of the Act directs the
Commission to approve a proposed rule
change of a self-regulatory organization
if it finds that such proposed rule
change is consistent with the
requirements of the Act and the rules
and regulations thereunder applicable to
such organization. Section 17A(b)(3)(F)
of the Act requires that the rules of a
clearing agency be designed to remove
impediments to the perfection of a
national system for the prompt and
accurate clearance and settlement of
securities transactions and are not
designed to permit unfair
discrimination in the admission of
participants or among participants in
the use of the clearing agency.5 The
Commission believes that NSCC’s rule
change, which refines NSCC’s rules and
procedures with regard to applicants
and members, is consistent with these
obligations and in general will protect
investors and the public interest.
pwalker on PROD1PC71 with NOTICES
IV. Conclusion
On the basis of the foregoing, the
Commission finds that the proposed
rule change is consistent with the
requirements of the Act and in
particular Section 17A of the Act and
the rules and regulations thereunder. In
approving the proposed rule change, the
Commission considered the proposal’s
impact on efficiency, competition, and
capital formation.
4 NSCC has also filed, and the Commission has
published notice of, proposed rule change SR–
NSCC–2006–17 which seeks to reorganize NSCC’s
rules related to membership standards and
membership requirements. Securities Exchange Act
Release No. 58100 (July 3, 2008), 73 FR 39759 (July
10, 2008) [SR–NSCC–2006–17].
5 15 U.S.C. 78q–1(b)(3)(F).
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:00 Dec 08, 2008
Jkt 217001
It is therefore ordered, pursuant to
Section 19(b)(2) of the Act, that the
proposed rule change (File No. SR–
NSCC–2007–08) be and hereby is
approved.
For the Commission by the Division of
Trading and Markets, pursuant to delegated
authority.6
Florence E. Harmon,
Acting Secretary.
[FR Doc. E8–29037 Filed 12–8–08; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 8011–01–P
SECURITIES AND EXCHANGE
COMMISSION
[Release No. 34–59039; File No. SR–
NYSEArca–2006–21]
Self-Regulatory Organizations; NYSE
Arca, Inc.; Order Setting Aside Action
by Delegated Authority and Approving
Proposed Rule Change Relating to
NYSE Arca Data
December 2, 2008.
On May 23, 2006, NYSE Arca, Inc.
(‘‘NYSE Arca’’ or ‘‘Exchange’’) filed
with the Securities and Exchange
Commission (‘‘Commission’’ or ‘‘SEC’’),
pursuant to section 19(b)(1) of the
Securities Exchange Act of 1934
(‘‘Exchange Act’’) 1 and Rule 19b–4
thereunder,2 a proposed rule change
(‘‘Proposal’’) to establish fees for the
receipt and use of certain market data
that the Exchange makes available. The
Proposal was published for comment in
the Federal Register on June 9, 2006.3
On October 12, 2006, the Commission
issued an order, by delegated authority,
approving the Proposal.4 On November
6, 2006, NetCoalition (‘‘Petitioner’’)
submitted a notice, pursuant to Rule 430
of the Commission’s Rules of Practice,
indicating its intention to file a petition
requesting that the Commission review
and set aside the Delegated Order.5 On
November 8, 2006, the Exchange
submitted a response to the Petitioner’s
Notice.6 On November 15, 2006,
Petitioner submitted its petition
requesting that the Commission review
6 17
CFR 200.30–3(a)(12).
U.S.C. 78s(b)(1).
2 17 CFR 240.19b–4.
3 Securities Exchange Act Release No. 53952
(June 7, 2006), 71 FR 33496 (June 9, 2006).
4 Securities Exchange Act Release No. 54597
(October 12, 2006) 71 FR 62029 (October 20, 2006)
(‘‘Delegated Order’’).
5 Letter from Markham C. Erikson, Executive
Director and General Counsel, NetCoalition, to the
Honorable Christopher Cox, Chairman, SEC, dated
November 6, 2006 (‘‘Notice’’).
6 Letter from Mary Yeager, Corporate Secretary,
NYSE Arca Inc., to the Honorable Christopher Cox,
Chairman, SEC, dated November 8, 2006 (‘‘NYSE
ARCA Petition Response’’).
1 15
PO 00000
Frm 00088
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
and set aside the Delegated Order.7 On
December 27, 2006, the Commission
issued an order: (1) Granting Petitioner’s
request for the Commission to review
the Delegated Order; (2) allowing any
party or other person to file a statement
in support of or in opposition to the
action made by delegated authority; and
(3) continuing the effectiveness of the
automatic stay provided in Rule 431(e)
of the Commission’s Rules of Practice.8
The Commission received 25 comments
regarding the Petition.9
On June 4, 2008, the Commission
published notice of a proposed order
(‘‘Draft Order’’) approving the NYSE
Arca proposed fees to give the public an
additional opportunity to comment.10
The Commission received 16 comments
and three economic assessments in
response to the Draft Order.
The Commission has considered the
Petition, comments, and economic
assessments submitted in response to
the Proposal, Petition, and Draft Order.
For the reasons described below, it is
setting aside the earlier action taken by
delegated authority and approving the
Proposal directly.
Table of Contents
I. Introduction
II. Description of Proposal
III. Summary of Comments Received
A. Commenters Opposing the Action by
Delegated Authority
1. Need for a Comprehensive Review of
Market Data Issues
2. Need for a Cost-Based Justification of
Market Data Fees
3. Exchange Act Rule 19b–4 Process
4. Importance of Depth-of-Book Data
5. Lack of Competition in Market Data
Pricing
6. Increase in Market Data Revenues
7. Recommended Solutions
B. Commenters Supporting the Action by
Delegated Authority
IV. NYSE Arca Responses to Commenters
A. Response to Commenters on Proposal
B. Response to Commenters on Petition
V. Comments on the Draft Order
VI. Discussion
A. Commission Review of Proposals for
Distributing Non-Core Data
B. Review of Competitive Forces
Applicable to NYSE Arca
1. Competition for Order Flow
2. Availability of Alternatives to ArcaBook
Data
7 Petition for Commission Review submitted by
Petitioner, dated November 14, 2006 (‘‘Petition’’).
8 Securities Exchange Act Release No. 55011
(December 27, 2006).
9 The comments on the Petition, as well as the
earlier comments on the Proposal, are identified
and summarized in section III below. NYSE Arca’s
responses to the commenters are summarized in
section IV below. Comments on the Draft Order are
summarized in section V below.
10 Securities Exchange Act Release No. 57917
(June 4, 2008), 73 FR 32751 (June 10, 2008) (‘‘Draft
Order’’).
E:\FR\FM\09DEN1.SGM
09DEN1
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 237 / Tuesday, December 9, 2008 / Notices
pwalker on PROD1PC71 with NOTICES
3. Response to Commenters on
Competition Issues
4. Response to Economic Assessments of
the Draft Order
a. Order Flow and Market Data
Competition
b. Substitutes for Depth-of-Book Data
c. Efficacy of Regulatory Alternatives
C. Review of Terms of the Proposal
VII. Conclusion
I. Introduction
The Commission’s Rules of Practice
set forth procedures for the review of
actions made pursuant to delegated
authority. Rule 431(b)(2) provides that
the Commission, in deciding whether to
accept or decline a discretionary review,
will consider the factors set forth in
Rule 411(b)(2). One of these factors is
whether an action pursuant to delegated
authority embodies a decision of law or
policy that is important and that the
Commission should review.
The Petitioner and commenters raised
a number of important issues that the
Commission believes it should address
directly at this time. In particular,
section VI below addresses issues
related to the nature of the
Commission’s review of proposed rule
changes for the distribution of ‘‘noncore’’ market data, which includes the
NYSE Arca data that is the subject of the
Proposal. Individual exchanges and
other market participants distribute
non-core data independently. Non-core
data should be contrasted with ‘‘core’’
data—the best-priced quotations and
last sale information of all markets in
U.S.-listed equities that Commission
rules require to be consolidated and
distributed to the public by a single
central processor.11 Pursuant to the
authority granted by Congress under
section 11A of the Exchange Act, the
Commission requires the self-regulatory
organizations (‘‘SROs’’) to participate in
joint-industry plans for disseminating
core data, and requires broker-dealers
and vendors to display core data to
investors to help inform their trading
and order-routing decisions. In contrast,
no Commission rule requires exchanges
or market participants either to
distribute non-core data to the public or
to display non-core data to investors.
Price transparency is critically
important to the efficient functioning of
the equity markets. In 2006, the core
data feeds reported prices for more than
$39.4 trillion in transactions in U.S.listed equities.12 In 2006, U.S. brokerdealers earned $21.7 billion in
commissions from trading in U.S.-listed
11 See section VI.A below for a fuller discussion
of the arrangements for distributing core and noncore data.
12 Source: ArcaVision (available at https://
www.arcavision.com).
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:00 Dec 08, 2008
Jkt 217001
equities—an amount that does not
include any revenues from proprietary
trading by U.S. broker-dealers or other
market participants.13 Approximately
420,000 securities industry
professionals subscribe to the core data
products of the joint-industry plans,
while only about 5% of these
professionals have chosen to subscribe
to the non-core data products of
exchanges.14
In June 2008, NYSE Arca executed a
16.5% share of trading in U.S.-listed
equities.15 The reasonably projected
revenues from the proposed fees for
NYSE Arca’s non-core data are $8
million per year.16 Commenters
opposing the Proposal claimed that
NYSE Arca exercised monopoly power
to set excessive fees for its non-core data
and recommended that the Commission
adopt a ‘‘cost-of-service’’ ratemaking
approach when reviewing exchange fees
for non-core data—an approach
comparable to the one traditionally
applied to utility monopolies.17
In 2005, however, the Commission
stated its intention to apply a marketbased approach that relies primarily on
competitive forces to determine the
terms on which non-core data is made
available to investors.18 This approach
follows the clear intent of Congress in
adopting section 11A of the Exchange
Act that, whenever possible,
competitive forces should dictate the
services and practices that constitute the
U.S. national market system for trading
equity securities. Section VI discusses
this market-based approach and applies
it in the specific context of the Proposal
by NYSE Arca. The Commission is
approving the Proposal primarily
because NYSE Arca was subject to
significant competitive forces in setting
the terms of the Proposal. The
Commission believes that reliance on
competitive forces, whenever possible,
is the most effective means to assess
whether proposed fees for non-core data
meet the applicable statutory
requirements.
The Petitioner and commenters
discussed and recommended solutions
for a wide range of market data issues
that were beyond the scope of the
Proposal. The Petitioner particularly
13 Frank A. Fernandez, Securities Industry and
Financial Markets Association Research Report,
‘‘Securities Industry Financial Results: 2006’’ (May
2, 2006) (‘‘SIFMA Research Report’’), at 7–9, 21.
14 See note 233 below and accompanying text.
15 See note 205 below and accompanying text.
16 See note 318 below and accompanying text.
17 The commenters’ views are summarized in
section III.A.2 below.
18 Securities Exchange Act Release No. 51808
(June 9, 2005), 70 FR 37496, 37566–37568 (June 29,
2005) (‘‘Regulation NMS Release’’).
PO 00000
Frm 00089
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
74771
called attention to the data needs of
users of advertiser-supported Internet
Web sites, many of whom are individual
retail investors. In this regard, the
Commission recognizes that exchanges
have responded by developing
innovative new data products
specifically designed to meet the
reference data needs and economic
circumstances of these Internet users.19
As noted in section III.A.1 below,
some commenters also suggested that,
pending a comprehensive resolution of
all market data issues (including those
related to core data), the Commission
should impose a moratorium on all
proposed rule changes related to market
data. The Commission recognizes the
importance of many of the issues raised
by commenters relating to core data that
are beyond the scope of the Proposal. It
is continuing to consider these issues,
and others, as part of its ongoing review
of SRO structure, governance, and
transparency.20 The Commission does
not, however, believe that imposing a
moratorium on the review of proposed
rule changes related to market data
products and fees would be appropriate
or consistent with the Exchange Act. A
primary Exchange Act objective for the
national market system is to promote
fair competition.21 Failing to act on the
proposed rule changes of particular
exchanges would be inconsistent with
this Exchange Act objective, as well as
with the requirements pertaining to SRO
rule filings more generally. Accordingly,
the Commission will continue to act on
proposed rule changes for the
distribution of market data in
accordance with the applicable
Exchange Act requirements.
II. Description of Proposal
Through NYSE Arca, LLC, the
equities trading facility of NYSE Arca
Equities, Inc., the Exchange makes
available on a real-time basis
ArcaBookSM, a compilation of all limit
orders resident in the NYSE Arca limit
order book. In addition, the Exchange
makes available real-time information
relating to transactions and limit orders
in debt securities that are traded
19 See Securities Exchange Act Release No. 57966
(June 16, 2008), 73 FR 35182 (June 20, 2008) (File
No. SR–NYSE–2007–04) (NYSE Real-Time
Reference Prices); Securities Exchange Act Release
No. 57965 (June 16, 2008), 73 FR 35178 (June 20,
2008) (SR–NASDAQ–2006–060) (Nasdaq Last Sale
Data Feeds).
20 See Securities Exchange Act Release No. 50699
(November 18, 2004), 69 FR 71126 (December 8,
2004) (proposed rules addressing SRO governance
and transparency); Securities Exchange Act Release
No. 50700 (November 18, 2004), 69 FR 71256
(December 8, 2004) (‘‘Concept Release Concerning
Self-Regulation’’).
21 Section 11A(a)(1)(C)(ii) of the Exchange Act, 15
U.S.C. 78k–1(a)(1)(C)(ii).
E:\FR\FM\09DEN1.SGM
09DEN1
74772
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 237 / Tuesday, December 9, 2008 / Notices
pwalker on PROD1PC71 with NOTICES
through the Exchange’s facilities. The
Exchange makes ArcaBook and the bond
transaction and limit order information
(collectively, ‘‘NYSE Arca Data’’)
available to market data vendors,
broker-dealers, private network
providers, and other entities by means
of data feeds. Currently, the Exchange
does not charge fees for the receipt and
use of NYSE Arca Data.
The Exchange’s proposal would
establish fees for the receipt and use of
NYSE Arca Data. Specifically, the
Exchange proposes to establish a $750
per month access fee for access to the
Exchange’s data feeds that carry the
NYSE Arca Data. In addition, the
Exchange proposes to establish
professional and non-professional
device fees for the NYSE Arca Data.22
For professional subscribers, the
Exchange proposes to establish a
monthly fee of $15 per device for the
receipt of ArcaBook data relating to
exchange-traded funds (‘‘ETFs’’) and
those equity securities for which
reporting is governed by the CTA Plan
(‘‘CTA Plan and ETF Securities’’) and a
monthly fee of $15 per device for the
receipt of ArcaBook data relating to
those equity securities, excluding ETFs,
for which reporting is governed by the
Nasdaq UTP Plan (‘‘Nasdaq UTP Plan
Securities’’).23 For non-professional
subscribers, the Exchange proposes to
establish a monthly fee of $5 per device
for the receipt of ArcaBook data relating
to CTA Plan and ETF Securities and a
monthly fee of $5 per device for the
receipt of ArcaBook data relating to
Nasdaq UTP Plan Securities.24
The Exchange also proposes a
maximum monthly payment for device
fees paid by any broker-dealer for nonprofessional subscribers that maintain
brokerage accounts with the brokerdealer.25 For 2006, the Exchange
22 In differentiating between professional and
non-professional subscribers, the Exchange
proposes to apply the same criteria used by the
Consolidated Tape Association Plan (‘‘CTA Plan’’)
and the Consolidated Quotation Plan (‘‘CQ Plan’’)
for qualification as a non-professional subscriber.
The two plans, which have been approved by the
Commission, are available at https://
www.nysedata.com.
23 The ‘‘Nasdaq UTP Plan’’ is the Joint SelfRegulatory Organization Plan Governing the
Collection, Consolidation and Dissemination of
Quotation and Transaction Information for NasdaqListed Securities Traded on Exchanges on an
Unlisted Trading Privileges Basis. The plan, which
has been approved by the Commission, is available
at https://www.utpdata.com.
24 There will be no monthly device fees for limit
order and last sale price information relating to debt
securities traded through the Exchange’s facilities.
25 Professional subscribers may be included in the
calculation of the monthly maximum amount so
long as: (1) Nonprofessional subscribers comprise
no less than 90% of the pool of subscribers that are
included in the calculation; (2) each professional
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:00 Dec 08, 2008
Jkt 217001
proposed a $20,000 maximum monthly
payment. For the months falling in a
subsequent calendar year, the maximum
monthly payment will increase (but not
decrease) by the percentage increase (if
any) in the annual composite share
volume 26 for the calendar year
preceding that subsequent calendar
year, subject to a maximum annual
increase of five percent.
Lastly, the Exchange proposes to
waive the device fees for ArcaBook data
during the duration of the billable
month in which a subscriber first gains
access to the data.
III. Summary of Comments Received
The Commission received four
comments from three commenters
regarding the Proposal after it was
published for comment.27 NYSE Arca
responded to the comments.28 After
granting the Petition, the Commission
received 25 comments from 17
commenters regarding the approval of
the Proposal by delegated authority.29
subscriber that is included in the calculation is not
affiliated with the broker-dealer or any of its
affiliates (either as an officer, partner or employee
or otherwise); and (3) each such professional
subscriber maintains a brokerage account directly
with the broker-dealer (that is, with the brokerdealer rather than with a correspondent firm of the
broker-dealer).
26 ‘‘Composite share volume’’ for a calendar year
refers to the aggregate number of shares in all
securities that trade over NYSE Arca facilities for
that calendar year.
27 Web comment from Steven C. Spencer, dated
June 18, 2006 (‘‘Spencer Letter’’); letter from
Markham C. Erickson, Executive Director and
General Counsel, NetCoalition, to Christopher Cox,
Chairman, Commission, dated August 9, 2006
(‘‘NetCoalition I’’); and letters from Gregory Babyak,
Chairman, Market Data Subcommittee of the
Securities Industry Association (‘‘SIA’’) Technology
and Regulation Committee, and Christopher
Gilkerson, Chairman, SIA Technology and
Regulation Committee, to Nancy Morris, Secretary,
Commission, dated June 30, 2006 (‘‘SIFMA I’’) and
August 18, 2006 (‘‘SIFMA II’’). The SIA has merged
into the Securities Industry and Financial Markets
Association (‘‘SIFMA’’).
28 Letters from Janet Angstadt, Acting General
Counsel, NYSE Arca, to Nancy J. Morris, Secretary,
Commission, dated July 25, 2006 (‘‘NYSE Arca
Response I’’), and August 25, 2006 (‘‘NYSE Arca
Response II’’).
29 Letters from Christopher Gilkerson and Gregory
Babyak, Co-Chairs, Market Data Subcommittee of
SIFMA Technology and Regulation Committee,
dated February 14, 2008 (‘‘SIFMA VIII’’); Ira D.
Hammerman, Senior Managing Director and
General Counsel, SIFMA, dated February 7, 2007
(‘‘SIFMA VII’’); Markham C. Erickson, Executive
Director and General Counsel, NetCoalition, dated
January 11, 2008 (‘‘NetCoalition V’’); The Honorable
Paul E. Kanjorski, Chairman, Subcommittee on
Capital Markets, Insurance, and Government
Sponsored Enterprises, dated December 12, 2007
(‘‘Kanjorski Letter’’); Melissa MacGregor, Vice
President and Assistant General Counsel, SIFMA,
dated November 7, 2007 (‘‘SIFMA VI’’); The
Honorable Richard H. Baker, Member of Congress,
dated October 1, 2007 (‘‘Baker Letter’’); Markham C.
Erickson, Executive Director and General Counsel,
NetCoalition, dated September 14, 2007
PO 00000
Frm 00090
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
Nine commenters urged the
Commission to set aside the action by
delegated authority,30 and five
commenters supported the action by
delegated authority.31 One commenter
expressed no views regarding the
specifics of the Proposal, but urged the
Commission to address market data fees
as part of a more comprehensive
modernization of SROs in light of recent
market structure developments.32 NYSE
Arca responded to the comments
submitted after the Commission granted
the Petition.33 Three commenters
submitted additional comments
(‘‘NetCoalition IV’’); Ira D. Hammerman, Senior
Managing Director and General Counsel, SIFMA,
dated August 1, 2007 (‘‘SIFMA V’’); Jeffrey Davis,
Vice President and Deputy General Counsel, The
Nasdaq Stock Market (‘‘Nasdaq’’), dated May 18,
2007 (‘‘Nasdaq Letter’’); David T. Hirschmann,
Senior Vice President, Chamber of Commerce of the
United States of America, dated May 3, 2007
(‘‘Chamber of Commerce Letter’’); Markham C.
Erickson, Executive Director and General Counsel,
NetCoalition, dated March 6, 2007 (‘‘NetCoalition
III’’); Ira D. Hammerman, Senior Managing Director
and General Counsel, SIFMA, dated March 5, 2007
(‘‘SIFMA IV’’); Joseph Rizzello, Chief Executive
Officer, National Stock Exchange (‘‘NSX’’), dated
February 27, 2007 (‘‘NSX Letter’’); Keith F. Higgins,
Chair, Committee on Federal Regulation of
Securities, American Bar Association (‘‘ABA’’),
dated February 12, 2007 (‘‘ABA Letter’’); James A.
Forese, Managing Director and Head of Global
Equities, Citigroup Global Markets Inc.
(‘‘Citigroup’’), dated February 5, 2007 (‘‘Citigroup
Letter’’); Meyer S. Frucher, Chairman and Chief
Executive Officer, PHLX, dated January 31, 2007
(‘‘PHLX Letter’’); Amex, Boston Stock Exchange,
Chicago Board Options Exchange, Chicago Stock
Exchange, ISE, The Nasdaq Stock Market, NYSE,
NYSE Arca, and Philadelphia Stock Exchange
(‘‘PHLX’’) (collectively, the ‘‘Exchange Market Data
Coalition’’), dated January 26, 2007 (‘‘Exchange
Market Data Coalition Letter’’); Oscar N. Onyema,
Senior Vice President and Chief Administrative
Officer, American Stock Exchange LLC (‘‘Amex’’),
dated January 18, 2007 (‘‘Amex Letter’’); Sanjiv
Gupta, Bloomberg, dated January 17, 2007
(‘‘Bloomberg Letter’’); Richard M. Whiting,
Executive Director and General Counsel, Financial
Services Roundtable, dated January 17, 2007
(‘‘Financial Services Roundtable Letter’’); Markham
C. Erickson, Executive Director and General
Counsel, NetCoalition, dated January 17, 2007
(‘‘NetCoalition II’’); Michael J. Simon, Secretary,
International Securities Exchange, LLC (‘‘ISE’’),
dated January 17, 2007 (‘‘ISE Letter’’); Jeffrey T.
Brown, Senior Vice President, Office of Legislative
and Regulatory Affairs, Charles Schwab & Co., Inc.
(‘‘Schwab’’), dated January 17, 2007 (‘‘Schwab
Letter’’); and Ira Hammerman, Senior Managing
Director and General Counsel, SIFMA, dated
January 17, 2007 (‘‘SIFMA III’’); and letter from
David Keith, Vice President, Web Products and
Solutions, The Globe and Mail, to the Honorable
Christopher Cox, Chairman, Commission, dated
January 17, 2007 (‘‘Globe and Mail Letter’’).
30 SIFMA III and IV, and Bloomberg, Chamber of
Commerce, Citigroup, Financial Services
Roundtable, Globe and Mail, NetCoalition, NSX,
and Schwab Letters.
31 Amex, Exchange Market Data Coalition, ISE,
Nasdaq, and PHLX Letters.
32 ABA Letter at 1.
33 Letter from Mary Yeager, Corporate Secretary,
NYSE Arca, to the Honorable Christopher Cox,
Chairman, Commission, dated February 6, 2007
(‘‘NYSE Arca Response III’’).
E:\FR\FM\09DEN1.SGM
09DEN1
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 237 / Tuesday, December 9, 2008 / Notices
addressing NYSE Arca’s response and
arguments raised by other commenters,
or provided additional information.34
The comments submitted in
connection with the Proposal and the
Petition are summarized in this section.
NYSE Arca’s responses are summarized
in section IV below.
A. Commenters Opposing the Action by
Delegated Authority
1. Need for a Comprehensive Review of
Market Data Issues
pwalker on PROD1PC71 with NOTICES
Several commenters seeking a reversal
of the staff’s approval of the Proposal by
delegated authority believed that recent
regulatory and market structure
developments warrant a broader review
of market data fees and of the
Commission’s procedures for reviewing
and evaluating market data proposals.35
According to these commenters, these
developments include the
transformation of most U.S. securities
exchanges into for-profit entities; the
increasing importance of single-market
depth-of-book information following
decimalization and the adoption of
Regulation NMS; and the absence of
competitive forces that could limit the
fees that an exchange may charge for its
depth-of-book data. Some commenters
believed that the Commission should
consider not only market data fees, but
also the contract terms governing the
use of an exchange’s market data, which
may impose additional costs and
include restrictions on the use of the
data.36
In light of the significance and
complexity of the issues raised, several
commenters asked the Commission not
only to reverse the staff’s action, but
also to impose a moratorium on the
approval or processing of market data
proposals while the Commission
conducts a broader review of the issues
associated with market data, including
‘‘the underlying issues of market
structure, market power, transparency,
and ease of dissemination and analysis
of market data.’’ 37
34 Nasdaq Letter; SIFMA IV, V, and VI;
NetCoalition III and IV.
35 Citigroup Letter at 2; SIFMA III at 10, 26;
SIFMA IV at 15. See also ABA Letter at 1;
Bloomberg Letter at 7–8; NetCoalition I at 2;
NetCoalition III at 13. Among other things, the
Bloomberg and Citigroup Letters support the
recommendations in SIFMA III. Bloomberg Letter at
8 n. 19; Citigroup Letter at 1.
36 Citigroup Letter at 2; SIFMA III at 23.
37 Citigroup Letter at 2. See also ABA Letter at 3;
Financial Services Roundtable Letter at 1;
NetCoalition III at 13; Schwab Letter at 1; SIFMA
III at 26; SIFMA IV at 15.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:00 Dec 08, 2008
Jkt 217001
74773
Similarly, a commenter stated that the
Commission acknowledged in its
Concept Release Concerning SelfSeveral commenters argued that the
Regulation that the amount of market
staff erred in approving the Proposal
data revenues should be reasonably
because NYSE Arca did not provide a
related to the cost of market
cost-based justification for the
information.46 Another commenter,
Proposal’s market data fees or other
citing proceedings involving Instinet’s
evidence to demonstrate that its
challenge to proposed NASD market
proposed fees meet the applicable
data fees,47 argued that the Commission
Exchange Act standards.38 They
in that case ‘‘emphatically embraced the
asserted that the Exchange Act requires
cost-based approach to setting market
that an exchange’s market data fees be
data fees * * *,’’ and insisted on a strict
‘‘fair and reasonable,’’ ‘‘not
cost-based justification for the market
unreasonably discriminatory,’’ and ‘‘an
data fees at issue.48
equitable allocation of costs,’’ 39 and that
The commenters believed, further,
the Commission apply a cost-based
that the costs attributable to market data
standard in evaluating market data
should be limited to the cost of
fees.40 One commenter argued that
collecting, consolidating, and
market data fees ‘‘must be reasonably
distributing the data,49 and that market
related to market data costs’’ and that
data fees should not be used to fund
the Commission should require
regulatory activities or to crossexchanges to identify and substantiate
subsidize an exchange’s competitive
their market data costs in their market
operations.50 One commenter
data fee proposals.41
maintained that, in the absence of cost
data, the Commission cannot determine
Several commenters argued that the
whether NYSE Arca uses market data
Commission itself has recognized the
revenues to subsidize competitive
need for a cost-based justification of
activities.51 In particular, the
market data fees.42 They believed that
commenter believed that the
the Commission’s position in its 1999
Commission must scrutinize the cost
market information concept release 43
justification for NYSE Arca’s fees to ‘‘be
‘‘underscores the fundamental role that
a rigorous cost-based analysis must play sure that NYSE Arca is not using its
market power in the upstream data
in reviewing market data fee filings.’’ 44
market as the exclusive processor for
In particular, these commenters cited
this data * * * to price squeeze its
the following statement from the
competitors in the downstream
release:
transaction market and to cross[T]he fees charged by a monopolistic
subsidize its reduction in transaction
provider of a service (such as the exclusive
fees.’’ 52
processors of market information) need to be
One commenter argued that NYSE
tied to some type of cost-based standard in
Arca’s proposed fees are not an
order to preclude excessive profits if fees are
‘‘equitable allocation’’ of costs among its
too high or underfunding or subsidization if
fees are too low. The Commission therefore
users and are unreasonably
believes that the total amount of market
discriminatory because the fees are
information revenues should remain
based on the number of people who
reasonably related to the cost of market
view the data. Thus, a broker-dealer
information.45
with many customers seeking to view
2. Need for a Cost-Based Justification of
Market Data Fees
38 Bloomberg Letter at 3; Petition at 5; SIFMA I
at 6; SIFMA III at 20.
39 Schwab Letter at 4; SIFMA III at 19; SIFMA IV
at 7.
40 Bloomberg Letter at 2; NetCoalition II at 3;
NetCoalition III at 11; Schwab Letter at 3; SIFMA
I at 6; SIFMA III at 16; SIFMA IV at 10.
41 SIFMA III at 1, 20.
42 Bloomberg Letter at 2; NetCoalition II at 3;
NetCoalition III at 11; Schwab Letter at 3; SIFMA
III at 20; SIFMA IV at 10.
43 Securities Exchange Act Release No. 42208
(December 9, 1999), 64 FR 70613 (December 17,
1999) (‘‘Market Information Concept Release’’).
44 NetCoalition II at 3. See also Bloomberg Letter
at 2; SIFMA I at 6.
45 64 FR at 70627 (cited in Bloomberg Letter at 2;
NetCoalition II at 3; NetCoalition III at 11 n. 47;
SIFMA III at 1). One commenter maintained that the
cost-based analysis requirement is based on
Congressional concerns regarding the dangers of
exclusive processors, in the context of either
consolidated or single-market data. NetCoalition II
at 3.
PO 00000
Frm 00091
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
46 NetCoalition
III at 11 n. 47.
Exchange Act Release No. 20874
(April 17, 1984), 49 FR 17640 (April 24, 1984), aff’d
sub nom. NASD, Inc. v. SEC, 802 F.2d 1415 (D.C.
Cir. 1986).
48 SIFMA IV at 10.
49 Citigroup Letter at 1; SIFMA III at 21. One
commenter believed that the Commission ‘‘should
create standards that allow producers of market
data to recover their costs and make a reasonable
profit (e.g., a 10% return), but not an excessive
profit.’’ Schwab Letter at 6.
50 SIFMA III at 8; SIFMA IV at 10. The commenter
believed that other costs, including member
regulation and market surveillance, should be
funded by listing, trading, and regulatory fees,
rather than market data fees. See SIFMA III at 21.
Another commenter maintained that funding
regulatory activities through an explicit regulatory
fee, rather than through market data revenues,
‘‘would be more logical and transparent * * *.’’
NSX Letter at 2. See also Schwab Letter at 5.
51 SIFMA IV at 10.
52 SIFMA IV at 10.
47 Securities
E:\FR\FM\09DEN1.SGM
09DEN1
74774
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 237 / Tuesday, December 9, 2008 / Notices
market data pays considerably more for
market data than an institution or
algorithmic trader that pays only for the
data link to its computer systems.53
3. Exchange Act Rule 19b–4 Process
pwalker on PROD1PC71 with NOTICES
One commenter argued that the
Proposal fails to satisfy the requirements
of Exchange Act Rule 19b–4 and Form
19b–4, because, among other things, the
Proposal does not: (1) Explain why
NYSE Arca must charge for data that it
previously provided free of charge; (2)
address the change in circumstances
caused by the NYSE’s conversion from
a member-owned, not-for-profit entity to
a shareholder-owned, for-profit entity;
(3) address the effect of the fee on retail
investors, whom the commenter
believes will be denied access to NYSE
Arca’s data as a result of the fees; (4)
explain how making available a faster
single-market data feed at a high price,
while most investors must rely on
slower consolidated market data
products, is consistent with the
mandates under the Exchange Act for
equal access to and transparency in
market data; and (5) include the contract
terms governing access to and use of
NYSE Arca’s data or address the
administrative costs and burdens that
the contract terms impose.54 Another
commenter, citing the Petition, asserted
that the Proposal fails to satisfy the
requirements of Form 19b–4 because it
provides no disclosure regarding the
burdens on competition that could
result from its proposed fees or a
justification for the proposed fees.55
Commenters also raised more general
concerns regarding the Exchange Act
Rule 19b–4 rule filing process as it
applies to proposed rule changes
relating to market data. In light of the
significant policy issues that market
data proposals raise, commenters
questioned whether such proposals
should be eligible to be effective upon
filing pursuant to Exchange Act Rule
19b–4(f)(6).56 One commenter believed
that all market data proposals should be
subject to notice and comment, and that
the Commission should provide a 30day comment period for such
proposals.57 In addition, the commenter
cautioned that the rule filing process
should not become a ‘‘rubberstamp’’ of
53 Schwab Letter at 4. The commenter argued that
this fee structure ‘‘is a subsidization program
whereby exchanges rebate revenue to their favored
traders based on market data fees imposed on retail
investors.’’ Id.
54 SIFMA III at 11–12.
55 Bloomberg Letter at 3. See also Petition at 6–
7.
56 Baker Letter at 1–2; SIFMA III at 22; Bloomberg
Letter at 6.
57 SIFMA III at 22.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:00 Dec 08, 2008
Jkt 217001
an exchange’s proposal.58 One
commenter suggested that the
Commission narrow its delegation of
authority with respect to proposed rule
changes to exclude proposals that have
generated significant public comment.59
4. Importance of Depth-of-Book Data
One commenter maintained that
because single-market depth-of-book
data products have significant
advantages over consolidated top-ofbook products in terms of both speed
and the depth of interest displayed,
many broker-dealers believe that it is
prudent to purchase single-market
depth-of-book data to satisfy their best
execution and Regulation NMS order
routing obligations.60 The commenter
noted that NYSE Arca has indicated in
its advertising materials that its
ArcaBook data feed is approximately 60
times faster than the consolidated data
feeds and displays six times the
liquidity within five cents of the inside
quote.61 The commenter also
maintained that the NYSE has linked its
depth-of-book products to best
execution by stating that ‘‘NYSE Arca’s
market data products are designed to
improve trade execution.’’ 62
One commenter argued that the
central processors that distribute
consolidated data have little incentive
to invest in modernizing their
operations.63 Another commenter
believed that the disparity between
faster and more expensive depth-ofbook proprietary data feeds and the
slower, less costly, and less valuable
consolidated data feeds results in a
‘‘two-tiered structure with institutions
having access to prices not reasonably
available to small investors * * *,’’
circumstances that the commenter
believed ‘‘recreate the informational
advantage that once existed on the
physical floors of the open outcry
markets.’’ 64
58 SIFMA
I at 2 n. 3.
III at 3–4.
60 SIFMA III at 5–6. The commenter stated that
depth-of-book information has become more
important because of the reduction in liquidity at
the inside quote and the increase in quote volatility
since decimalization, and because depth-of-book
quotations are likely to become more executable
following the implementation of Regulation NMS.
SIFMA III at 12–13. Similarly, another commenter
maintained that, through Regulation NMS, the
Commission ‘‘has imposed a system that requires
access to depth-of-book information.’’ Schwab
Letter at 5. Likewise, a commenter believed that
market participants require depth-of-book
information to trade effectively in decimalized
markets. SIFMA IV at 8. See also NetCoalition III
at 5.
61 SIFMA III at 14 n. 24.
62 SIFMA IV at 12.
63 SIFMA III at 13.
64 Financial Services Roundtable Letter at 3. One
commenter believed that market participants who
59 NetCoalition
PO 00000
Frm 00092
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
Another commenter believed that
depth-of-book information should be
considered basic information for retail
investors as well as professional
investors and that one goal of the
National Market System should be to
assure that ‘‘all investors * * * whether
professional or non-professional * * *
have equal access to the same quality
information, at a reasonable price, and
at the same time.’’ 65 Similarly, a
commenter believed that retail investors
require quotations beyond the national
best bid or offer to assess the quality of
the executions they receive.66
5. Lack of Competition in Market Data
Pricing
Commenters argued that there are no
effective competitive or market forces
that limit what an exchange may charge
for its depth-of-book data.67 Although
one commenter acknowledged the
argument that competition in the market
for liquidity and transactions could
serve as a constraint on what exchanges
may charge for their data products, the
commenter believed that the
consolidations of the NYSE with
Archipelago and Nasdaq with BRUT
and INET have limited this constraint.68
The commenter also asserted that
competition in the market for order
execution is not the same as
competition in the market for market
data, and that an economic analysis
must consider the market for market
data from the consumer’s perspective.69
Because proprietary market data is a
‘‘sole-source product,’’ the commenter
believed that no market forces operate
on the transaction between an exchange
and the consumer of its data.70 The
commenter believed that the unique
characteristics of the market for market
data—including increased market
concentration and market participants’
obligation to purchase sole-source
proprietary market data to trade
effectively—resulted in a ‘‘classic
economic market failure * * * that
requires comprehensive regulatory
intervention to ensure ‘fair and
reasonable’ prices.’’ 71 Similarly,
another commenter maintained that,
choose not to purchase depth-of-book data will face
the informational disadvantages that Regulation
NMS seeks to eliminate. NSX Letter at 2.
65 SIFMA IV at 13.
66 NetCoalition III at 5 n. 16.
67 NetCoalition III at 9; SIFMA III at 16–17;
SIFMA IV at 5.
68 SIFMA III at 17.
69 SIFMA IV at 5. See also NetCoalition III at 2.
70 SIFMA IV at 5.
71 SIFMA IV at 8. The commenter believed that
Congress envisioned the Commission regulating
exclusive processors in a manner similar to the way
in which public utilities are regulated. SIFMA I at
5.
E:\FR\FM\09DEN1.SGM
09DEN1
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 237 / Tuesday, December 9, 2008 / Notices
with respect to market data that is
exclusive to an exchange, ‘‘[t]here is no
way for competitive forces to produce
market-driven or ‘fair and reasonable’
prices required by the Exchange Act
* * *.’’ 72
Other commenters believed that an
exchange has a monopoly position as
the exclusive processor of its
proprietary data that ‘‘creates a serious
potential for abusive pricing
practices,’’ 73 and urged the Commission
to consider the lack of competition and
the inability to obtain market data from
other sources.74 One commenter
asserted that ‘‘broker-dealers will * * *
be forced to purchase market data at a
fixed and * * * arbitrary price’’ until
market data fees are reformed.75
In addition, several commenters
believed that the transformation of most
U.S. securities exchanges from not-forprofit membership organizations to forprofit entities has eliminated an
important constraint on market data fees
as the for-profit exchanges seek to
maximize value for their shareholders.76
In this regard, one commenter explained
that ‘‘exchanges are beholden to their
shareholders to increase revenue, and
market data is the revenue stream that
holds the greatest potential for doing
so.’’ 77 Other commenters argued that
the advent of for-profit exchanges has
eliminated the governance checks on
market data pricing that operated when
exchange members—broker-dealers who
were obligated to purchase consolidated
market data—sat on the boards of the
non-profit, member-owned exchanges.78
6. Increase in Market Data Revenues
With respect to the increase in the
NYSE Group’s market data revenues
following its merger with Archipelago,
one commenter stated that ‘‘NYSE
Group’s reported market data segment
revenues totaled $57.5 million in the
third quarter of 2006: Up 33.7% from
the same three-month period in
72 NetCoalition
III at 2.
Letter at 6. See also Spencer Letter.
74 Citigroup Letter at 1. Similarly, a commenter
believed that ‘‘[u]nless checked by effective
regulatory oversight * * * exchanges have both the
incentives and the power to charge whatever they
can for the market data over which they have
exclusive control.’’ SIFMA III at 4. The commenter
also asserted that ‘‘[t]he lack of both economic
market forces and comprehensive oversight of
exchanges as the sole-source processors of market
data * * * has allowed the exchange to simply
‘name their prices’ * * *.’’ SIFMA IV at 2.
75 NSX Letter at 2.
76 ABA Letter at 2–3; Financial Services
Roundtable Letter at 2; Schwab Letter at 5; SIFMA
III at 24.
77 Schwab Letter at 5. See also NetCoalition II at
4; SIFMA III at 24; SIFMA IV at 2.
78 Financial Services Roundtable Letter at 2;
NetCoalition II at 4; SIFMA III at 15.
pwalker on PROD1PC71 with NOTICES
73 Schwab
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:00 Dec 08, 2008
Jkt 217001
2005.’’ 79 According to the commenter,
the NYSE Group attributed its revenue
growth in market data to the
contribution of NYSE Arca’s operations
following the completion of the merger
between the NYSE and Archipelago on
March 7, 2006.80 The commenter
maintained that Nasdaq has experienced
similar growth in its market data
revenues and that the exchanges
‘‘propose to charge fees for a series of
market data products that, when
multiplied by the number of potential
subscribers, are resulting in increased
costs of doing business totaling tens of
millions of dollars per year for some
individual firms and hundreds of
millions of dollars per year across the
financial markets.’’ 81 The commenter
identified the current fees for
proprietary and consolidated market
data products and claimed that
investors ultimately pay these fees.82
7. Recommended Solutions
To address the issues raised by market
data fees, the commenters suggested
several potential solutions. One
commenter recommended that the
Commission adopt a specialized market
data form for market data rule proposals
that would require a detailed
justification of proposed fee changes by
the SROs.83 The commenter believed
that the form should, among other
things, require an exchange to
substantiate its historical costs of
producing market data, its current
market data revenues, how and why its
costs have changed and the existing
revenue is no longer appropriate, how
the fee would impact market
participants, how the revenues would
be used, and the contract terms, system
specifications, and audit requirements
that would be associated with the
proposed fee change.84
The commenter also believed that the
contract terms governing the use of
market data should be included in
market data rule filings and subject to
notice and comment.85 The commenter
maintained that the contract terms are
effectively non-negotiable and that the
compliance costs associated with them
may affect the efficiency and
transparency of the markets. Another
commenter asserted that exchange
market data contracts limit the use and
dissemination of the data provided
under the contracts, potentially
79 SIFMA
III at 18–19 (citations omitted).
III at 18 (citation omitted).
81 SIFMA III at 4.
82 SIFMA IV at 14 and Appendix A.
83 SIFMA III at 21–22.
84 SIFMA III at 21–22.
85 SIFMA III at 23.
80 SIFMA
PO 00000
Frm 00093
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
74775
impairing the flow and further analysis
of the information, and impose
administrative and technological
burdens on firms.86
The commenters also suggested
structural changes to address market
data issues, including requiring
exchanges to place their market data
operations in a separate subsidiary and
to make their raw market data available
to third parties on the same terms as
they make the data available to their
market data subsidiary and to the
independent central processor.87 The
commenters believed that this could
encourage competition in providing
market data products and services 88 and
create a mechanism for free market
pricing.89
Finally, the commenters suggested
that the Commission increase the
quality and depth of the required
consolidated quotation information to
allow retail investors to determine the
prices at which their orders will be
executed and to observe pricing
movements in the market.90 One
commenter recommended that the
Commission require exchanges to
consolidate and distribute their top and
depth-of-book data, and that the
associated costs be paid by investors
who act on the information.91
B. Commenters Supporting the Action
by Delegated Authority
Several commenters who supported
the approval of the Proposal by
delegated authority argued that the staff
applied the correct legal standard 92 and
that the broader policy questions raised
by the Petition should be addressed in
the context of Commission rulemaking,
rather than in connection with a specific
exchange market data proposal.93
Several commenters rejected the
assertion that a cost-based standard is
the correct standard for the Commission
to apply in reviewing market data fee
proposals.94 In this regard, the
commenters distinguished between the
standards applicable to ‘‘core’’ market
data (i.e., consolidated quotation and
last sale data for U.S.-listed equities)
and the standards applicable to
86 Citigroup
Letter at 2.
Letter at 4; Kanjorski Letter at 1;
NetCoalition I at 2; Schwab Letter at 7; SIFMA III
at 24–25.
88 SIFMA III at 25.
89 Schwab Letter at 7.
90 Schwab Letter 5; SIFMA III at 25–26.
91 NSX Letter at 2. Other commenters endorse this
recommendation.NetCoalition III at 7, 13; SIFMA IV
at 15.
92 Amex Letter at 2; ISE Letter at 3; PHLX Letter
at 2–3.
93 Amex Letter at 4; PHLX Letter at 8.
94 Exchange Market Data Coalition Letter at 2; ISE
Letter at 3; PHLXLetter at 4.
87 Bloomberg
E:\FR\FM\09DEN1.SGM
09DEN1
74776
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 237 / Tuesday, December 9, 2008 / Notices
proprietary market data products.95 One
commenter maintained that the
Commission, in adopting Regulation
NMS, authorized exchanges to
distribute market data outside of the
national market system plans, subject to
the general fairness and
nondiscrimination standards of Rule
603 of Regulation NMS, but ‘‘otherwise
[left] to free market forces the
determination of what information
would be provided and at what
price.’’ 96 Another commenter, noting
that the Commission specifically
considered and refrained from adopting
the cost-based standard that
NetCoalition proposes, argued that
NetCoalition’s approach ‘‘would replace
Regulation NMS * * * with a complex
and intrusive rate-making approach that
is inconsistent with the goals of the
* * * [Exchange Act] and would be
more costly than beneficial.’’ 97
One commenter disagreed with the
assertion that an exchange possesses
monopoly pricing power with respect to
its proprietary data products. It
contended that assertions concerning an
exchange’s monopoly pricing power
‘‘ignore * * * market reality and market
discipline. If any exchange attempts to
charge excessive fees, there simply will
not be buyers for such products.’’ 98
Nasdaq noted that, as of April 30, 2007,
over 420,000 professional users
purchased core data, but less than
19,000 professional users purchased
TotalView, Nasdaq’s proprietary depthof-book order product.99 It concluded
that ‘‘[b]roker-dealers may claim they
are required to purchase TotalView, but
their actions indicate otherwise.’’ 100
The commenters emphasized that the
exchanges face significant competition
in their efforts to attract order flow:
pwalker on PROD1PC71 with NOTICES
Exchanges compete not only with one
another, but also with broker-dealers that
match customer orders within their own
95 Amex Letter at 1; ISE Letter at 2–3; PHLX Letter
at 4–5.
96 Amex Letter at 2. The commenter noted that
exchange fees also aresubject to the requirements of
Section 6(b)(4) of the Exchange Act. See also PHLX
Letter at 7.
97 Exchange Market Data Coalition Letter at 2.
One commenter asserted that ‘‘[a]pplying
NetCoalition’s proposed strict cost-based fee
analysis to every exchange market data rule filing
is unworkable and * * * is not required under the
Act.’’ ISE Letter at 3. Similarly, noting that SROs
must ensure that market data is not corrupted by
fraud or manipulation, another commenter believed
that it would be virtually impossible to identify the
costs specifically associated with the production of
market data versus other SRO functions. PHLX
Letter at 6.
98 ISE Letter at 3. Similarly, another commenter
noted that the users of data will purchase data ‘‘if
it provides them value and is priced reasonably.’’
Amex Letter at 1.
99 Nasdaq Letter at 6.
100 Nasdaq Letter at 6.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:00 Dec 08, 2008
Jkt 217001
systems and also with a proliferation of
alternative trading systems (‘‘ATSs’’) and
electronic communications networks
(‘‘ECNs’’) that the Commission has also
nurtured and authorized to execute trades in
any listed issue. As a result, market share of
trading fluctuates among execution facilities
based on their ability to service the end
customer. The execution business is highly
competitive and exhibits none of the
characteristics of a monopoly as suggested in
the NetCoalition Petition.101
Similarly, another commenter stated
that ‘‘the market for proprietary data
products is currently competitive and
inherently contestable because there is
fierce competition for the inputs
necessary to the creation of proprietary
data and strict pricing discipline for the
proprietary products themselves.’’ 102 It
also noted that market data ‘‘is the
totality of the information assets that
each Exchange creates by attracting
order flow’’ and emphasized that ‘‘[i]t is
in each Exchange’s best interest to
provide proprietary information to
investors to further their business
objectives, and each Exchange chooses
how best to do that.’’ 103 Commenters
stated that, in the absence of a
regulatory requirement to provide noncore market data, it is necessary to
provide a financial or other business
incentive for exchanges to make such
data available.104
IV. NYSE Arca Responses to
Commenters
A. Response to Commenters on Proposal
In its responses to commenters on the
Proposal, the Exchange argued that the
Proposal establishes ‘‘a framework for
distributing data in which all vendors
and end users are permitted to receive
and use the Exchange’s market data on
equal, non-discriminatory terms.’’ 105
The Exchange asserted that the
proposed professional and nonprofessional device fees for the NYSE
Arca Data were fair and reasonable
because they ‘‘are far lower than those
already established—and approved by
the Commission—for similar products
offered by other U.S. equity exchanges
and stock markets.’’ 106 In particular, the
Exchange noted that the proposed $15
per month device fee for each of the
ArcaBook data products is less than
both the $60 per month and $70 per
month device fees that the NYSE and
Nasdaq, respectively, charge for
comparable market data products.107
With respect to its proposed fees, the
Exchange noted, further, that it had
invested significantly in its ArcaBook
products, including making
technological enhancements that
allowed the Exchange to expand
capacity and improve processing
efficiency as message traffic increased,
thereby reducing the latency associated
with the distribution of ArcaBook
data.108 The Exchange stated that ‘‘[i]n
determining to invest the resources
necessary to enhance ArcaBook
technology, the Exchange contemplated
that it would seek to charge for the
receipt and use of ArcaBook data.’’ 109
The Exchange also emphasized the
reasonableness of its proposed fee
relative to other comparable market data
products, asserting, for example, that
‘‘NYSE Arca is at the inside price
virtually as often as Nasdaq, yet the
proposed fee for ArcaBook is merely
one-fifth of the TotalView fee.’’ 110
Moreover, it stated that its decision to
commence charging for ArcaBook data
was based on its view that ‘‘market data
charges are a particularly equitable
means for funding a market’s
investment in technology and its
operations. In contrast with transaction,
membership, listing, regulatory and
other SRO charges, market data charges
cause all consumers of a securities
market’s services, including investors
and market data vendors, to
contribute.’’ 111
The Exchange stated that it proposes
to use the CTA and CQ Plan contracts
to govern the distribution of NYSE Arca
Data and that it was not amending the
terms of these existing contracts or
imposing restrictions on the use or
display of its data beyond those that are
currently set forth in the contracts.112
Further, the Exchange specifically noted
that these contracts do not prohibit a
broker-dealer from making its own data
available outside of the CTA and CQ
Plans.113 Finally, the Exchange argued
that by using this current structure, it
believes that the administrative burdens
on firms and vendors should be low.114
B. Response to Commenters on Petition
In its response to commenters on the
Petition, the Exchange argued that
recent market-based solutions have
mooted the concerns expressed in the
107 NYSE
101 Exchange
Market Data Coalition Letter at 4.
102 Nasdaq Letter at 7.
103 Id. at 3, 4.
104 Amex Letter at 1; ISE Letter at 2; PHLX Letter
at 7.
105 NYSE Arca Response I at 2.
106 Id.
PO 00000
Frm 00094
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
Arca Response I at 2–3.
Arca Response II at 2.
109 Id. at 3.
110 Id.
111 Id. at 4.
112 NYSE Arca Response I at 3.
113 Id. at n. 12 and accompanying text.
114 Id. at 5.
108 NYSE
E:\FR\FM\09DEN1.SGM
09DEN1
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 237 / Tuesday, December 9, 2008 / Notices
Petition regarding the affordability of
market data for internet portals.115 In
particular, the Exchange noted that the
NYSE recently submitted a proposed
rule change for a market data product
that would provide unlimited real-time
last sale prices to vendors for a fixed
monthly fee (‘‘NYSE Internet
Proposal’’).116 The Exchange stated that
this NYSE Internet Proposal ‘‘would
meet the needs of internet portals and
add to the number of choices that are
available to intermediaries and investors
for their receipt of real-time prices.’’ 117
The Exchange asserted that the NYSE
Internet Proposal ‘‘provides a significant
benefit to investors’’ since ‘‘it adds to
the data-access alternatives available to
them and improves the quality,
timeliness and affordability of data they
can receive over the internet.’’ 118
The Exchange also reiterated the
argument that the proposed market data
fees meet the statutory standards for
such fees under the Exchange Act.119
The Exchange argued that the fees
represent an equitable allocation of fees
and charges since they ‘‘represent the
first time that [the Exchange] has
established a fee that a person or entity
other than an [Exchange] member or
listed company must pay’’ and are being
imposed ‘‘on those who use the
facilities of [the Exchange] but do not
otherwise contribute to [the Exchange’s]
operating costs.’’ 120
The Exchange argued that the
proposed market data fees are not
‘‘unreasonably discriminatory’’ since
‘‘all professional subscribers are subject
to the same fees and all nonprofessional
subscribers are subject to the same
fees.’’ 121 The Exchange noted that the
only discrimination that occurs is the
‘‘reasonable’’ distinction that would
require professional subscribers to pay
higher fees than nonprofessional
subscribers.122
The Exchange asserted that the fees
are fair and reasonable because: (1)
‘‘They compare favorably to the level of
fees that other U.S. markets and the
CTA and Nasdaq/UTP Plans impose for
comparable products’’; (2) ‘‘the quantity
and quality of data NYSE Arca includes
in Arca Book compares favorably to the
data that other markets include in their
market data products’’; and (3) ‘‘the fees
will enable NYSE Arca to recover the
resources that NYSE Arca devoted to the
pwalker on PROD1PC71 with NOTICES
115 NYSE
Arca Response III at 5–6.
id. at 5.
117 NYSE Arca Response III at 5.
118 Id.
119 Id. at 11.
120 Id.
121 Id.
122 Id.
116 See
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:00 Dec 08, 2008
Jkt 217001
technology necessary to produce Arca
Book data.’’ 123
The Exchange also rejected the
Petitioner’s assertion that the Exchange
acted ‘‘arbitrarily or capriciously’’ by
using a comparison of similar market
data fees in setting the level of the
proposed fees.124 The Exchange noted
that in addition to studying ‘‘what other
markets charge for comparable
products,’’ the Exchange also
considered: (1) The needs of those
entities that would likely purchase the
Arca Book data; (2) the ‘‘contribution
that revenues from Arca Book Fees
would make toward replacing the
revenues that NYSE Arca stands to lose
as a result of the removal of the NQDS
service from the Nasdaq/UTP Plan’’; (3)
‘‘the contribution that revenues accruing
from Arca Book Fees would make
toward NYSE Arca’s market data
business’’; (4) the contribution that
revenues accruing from Arca Book Fees
would make toward meeting the overall
costs of NYSE Arca’s operations’’; (5)
‘‘projected losses to NYSE Arca’s
business model and order flow that
might result from marketplace
resistance to Arca Book Fees’’; and (6)
‘‘the fact that Arca Book is primarily a
product for market professionals, who
have access to other sources of market
data and who will purchase Arca Book
only if they determine that the
perceived benefits outweigh the
cost.’’ 125
The Exchange also rejected the
Petitioner’s assertion that all proposed
market data fees must be subjected to a
rigorous cost-based analysis.126 The
Exchange noted that the Petitioner ‘‘is
able to cite only one instance’’ that
supports such an assertion.127 The
Exchange also noted that Petitioner
‘‘fails to mention that a significant
portion of the industry’’ expressed
opposition to a cost-based approach to
analyzing market data fees in response
to various Commission releases and
other initiatives.128 The Exchange
argued that a cost-based analysis of
market data fees is impractical because
‘‘[i]t would inappropriately burden both
the government and the industry, stifle
competition and innovation, and in the
123 Id.
at 11–12.
at 12.
125 Id. at 12–13.
126 Id. at 13.
127 Id.
128 Id. at 14–15. The Exchange referenced
opposition in the industry to a cost-based analysis
of market data fees expressed in connection with
the Market Information Concept Release, the
Concept Release Concerning Self-Regulation, the
Regulation NMS initiative, and the Commission’s
Advisory Committee on Market Information.
124 Id.
PO 00000
Frm 00095
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
74777
end, raise costs and, potentially,
fees.’’ 129
The Exchange also disputed
Petitioner’s argument that the
Exchange’s proposed market data fees
amount to an exercise of monopoly
pricing power.130 It noted that
‘‘[m]arkets compete with one another by
seeking to maximize the amount of
order flow that they attract. The markets
base the competition for order flow on
such things as technology, customer
service, transaction costs, ease of access,
liquidity and transparency.’’ 131 The
Exchange noted that ‘‘[t]he Commission
has prescribed top-of-the-book
consolidated market data as the data
required for best execution purposes’’
and that there is ‘‘no regulatory
requirement’’ for brokers to receive
depth-of-book or other proprietary
market data products.132 Accordingly,
the Exchange asserted that no monopoly
power exists, and that the marketplace
determines the fees charged by the
Exchange for depth-of-book market
data.133 Further, the Exchange claimed
that if the market data fees were
excessive, market participants ‘‘would
forego Arca Book data and would
choose to receive the depth-of-book
service of other markets.’’ 134 It noted
that:
As a result of all of the choices and
discretion that are available to brokers, the
displayed depth-of-book data of one trading
center does not provide a complete picture of
the full market for the security. It displays
only a portion of all interest in the security.
A brokerage firm has potentially dozens of
different information sources to choose from
in determining if, where, and how to
represent an order for execution.135
The Exchange also addressed other
concerns raised by commenters in
connection with the Petition. First, the
Exchange indicated that it has no
intention of retroactively imposing the
proposed market data fees.136 The
Exchange also disputed a commenter’s
statement which indicated that ‘‘market
data revenues of the NYSE Group (the
parent company of Exchange and NYSE)
for the third quarter of 2006 rose 33.7%
129 Id. at 15 (citing NYSE Response to Market
Information Concept Release (April 10, 2000))
(emphasis in original).
130 Id. at 16.
131 Id. at 16. See also id. at 18 (‘‘If too many
market professionals reject Arca Book as too
expensive, NYSE Arca would have to reassess the
Arca Book Fees because Arca Book data provides
transparency to NYSE Arca’s market, transparency
that plays an important role in the competition for
order flow.’’).
132 Id. at 18.
133 Id.
134 Id.
135 Id. at 17.
136 Id. at 20.
E:\FR\FM\09DEN1.SGM
09DEN1
74778
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 237 / Tuesday, December 9, 2008 / Notices
from the year-earlier.’’ 137 According to
the Exchange, this statistic does not
demonstrate ‘‘a significant increase in
market data revenues during 2006’’
since the 2005 market data revenue from
the NYSE Group used to generate this
statistic did not include the Exchange’s
market data revenue because the
Exchange was not part of the NYSE
Group in 2005.138 The Exchange notes
that the combined market data revenues
for the Exchange and NYSE have
actually declined slightly.139 Lastly, the
Exchange rejects the commenters’
contention that a significant speed
variance exists between proprietary
market data products and the
consolidated data feed that markets
make available under the CQ and
Nasdaq/UTP Plans. The Exchange notes
that the ‘‘variations in speed are
measured in milliseconds’’ and that
‘‘[f]rom a display perspective the
difference is imperceptible.’’ 140
Furthermore, the Exchange notes that
the CQ Plan participants have
undertaken a technology upgrade that
would reduce the latency of the
consolidated feed from ‘‘several
hundred milliseconds to approximately
30 milliseconds.’’ 141
V. Comments on the Draft Order
The Commission received 16
comments from 12 commenters
regarding the Draft Order,142 three of
137 Id.
pwalker on PROD1PC71 with NOTICES
138 Id.
139 Id. at n. 50 and accompanying text. According
to the Exchange, pro forma results indicate that the
Exchange and NYSE received a combined $242
million in 2005, while they only received a
combined $235 million in 2006.
140 Id. at 21.
141 Id.
142 Letters from Ira D. Hammerman, Senior
Managing Director and General Counsel, SIFMA,
dated November 17, 2008 (‘‘SIFMA X’’) (attaching
supplemental report by Securities Litigation &
Consulting Group, Inc.); Markham C. Erickson,
Executive Director and General Counsel,
NetCoalition, dated October 14, 2008 (‘‘NetCoalition
VII’’) (attaching report by Dr. David S. Evans dated
October 10, 2008); Bart M. Green, Chairman, and
John Giesea, President and CEO, Security Traders
Association (‘‘STA’’), dated September 11, 2008
(‘‘STA Letter’’); Jeffrey S. Davis, Vice President and
Deputy General Counsel, Nasdaq OMX Group, Inc.,
dated September 10, 2008 (‘‘Nasdaq III’’) and
August 1, 2008 (‘‘Nasdaq II’’); Joseph Rizzello, Chief
Executive Officer, NSX, dated September 9, 2008
(‘‘NSX II’’); Richard Bartlett, Managing Director,
Citigroup Global Markets Inc., dated July 11, 2008
(‘‘Citigroup II’’); David T. Hirschmann, President
and Chief Executive Officer, Center for Capital
Markets Competitiveness of the United States
Chamber of Commerce, dated July 10, 2008
(‘‘Chamber of Commerce II’’); Michael J. Simon,
Secretary, ISE, dated July 10, 2008 (‘‘ISE II’’);
Markham C. Erickson, Executive Director and
General Counsel, NetCoalition, dated July 10, 2008
(attaching report by Dr. David S. Evans)
(‘‘NetCoalition VI’’); Markham C. Erickson,
Executive Director and General Counsel,
NetCoalition, dated July 10, 2008 (‘‘NetCoalition
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:00 Dec 08, 2008
Jkt 217001
which also submitted economic studies
analyzing the Draft Order’s rationale for
approving the Proposal.143
NetCoalition and SIFMA did not
believe that the Draft Order’s analytical
framework would meet the
Commission’s responsibilities under the
Exchange Act for reviewing market data
fees.144 In this regard, SIFMA stated that
‘‘there is * * * no basis for the
presumption in the [Draft] Order that
[the] statutory requirements are satisfied
if the Commission is able to conclude
that ‘significant competitive forces’ exist
in the context of an exchange fee
proposal.’’ 145 NetCoalition asserted that
Congress urged the Commission not to
rely on competitive forces in the context
of exclusive processors of data.146
Some commenters questioned the
extent of exchange competition for order
flow and whether such competition
results in fair and reasonable market
data fees.147 The SLCG Study asserted
that competition for order flow does not
assure competitive pricing for depth-ofbook data and that reliance on
competitive forces was inappropriate
because the NYSE and Nasdaq exert
monopoly pricing power with respect to
their depth-of-book data.148 The Evans
Report maintained that order flow
competition is reflected in transaction
fees and liquidity rebates, which are
structured to attract order flow, but not
in depth-of-book data fees, which do not
V’’); Ira D. Hammerman, Senior Managing Director
and General Counsel, SIFMA, dated July 10, 2008
(attaching report by the Securities Litigation &
Consulting Group, Inc.) (‘‘SIFMA IX’’); Mary
Yeager, Corporate Secretary, NYSE Arca, to
Florence Harmon, Acting Secretary, Commission,
dated July 8, 2008 (‘‘NYSE Arca IV’’); and
Christopher Perry, Thomson Reuters Markets, dated
July 8, 2008 (‘‘Thomson Reuters Letter’’); and web
comments from William C. Martin, Principal, Indie
Research, LLC and Founder, RagingBull.com, dated
July 9, 2008 (‘‘Indie Research Comment’’); and Kreg
Rutherford (‘‘Rutherford Comment’’).
143 David S. Evans, ‘‘Response to Ordover and
Bamberger’s Statement Regarding the SEC’s
Proposed Order Concerning the Pricing of Depth-ofBook Market Data’’ (‘‘Evans II’’), which was
submitted with NetCoalition VII; David S. Evans,
‘‘An Economic Assessment of Whether ‘Significant
Competitive Forces’ Constrain an Exchange’s
Pricing of Its Depth-of-Book Market Data’’ (‘‘Evans
Report’’), which was submitted with NetCoalition
VI; Securities Litigation and Consulting Group, Inc.
(‘‘SLCG’’), ‘‘An Economic Study of Securities
Market Data Pricing by the Exchanges’’ (‘‘SLCG
Study’’), which was submitted with SIFMA IX and
a supplemental analysis to the SLCG Study (‘‘SLCG
II’’), which was submitted with SIFMA X; and
Statement of Janusz Ordover and Gustavo
Bamberger, dated August 1, 2008 (‘‘Ordover/
Bamberger Statement’’ or ‘‘Statement’’), which was
submitted with Nasdaq II.
144 NetCoalition V at 7–9; SIFMA IX at 9–11.
145 SIFMA IX at 10.
146 NetCoalition V at 9–10.
147 Citigroup II at 2; Indie Research Comment;
NetCoalition VI at 1; NSX II at 5; SIFMA IX at 3;
STA Letter at 3.
148 SLCG Study at 2 and 34.
PO 00000
Frm 00096
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
vary according to the data purchaser’s
trading volume.149 NetCoalition and
SIFMA also questioned whether the
Draft Order’s conclusion that depth-ofbook data is not necessary to meet a
broker-dealer’s duty of best execution
would be reached in other legal
contexts.150
Several commenters believed that the
NYSE and NYSE Arca must be
considered to be a single enterprise for
purposes of analyzing market power
with respect to depth-of-book data, and
that the Draft Order erred in treating
them as separate entities.151 In this
regard, the Evans Report found that,
because the NYSE and NYSE Arca are
controlled by a single corporate entity
that will coordinate the pricing of the
depth-of-book products of its
subsidiaries to maximize its own profits,
the NYSE’s depth-of-book data cannot
act as a competitive constraint on the
pricing of NYSE Arca’s depth-of-book
data.152
Commenters opposing the Draft Order
also believed that the Commission must
obtain and analyze data regarding NYSE
Arca’s costs of collecting and
disseminating depth-of-book
information to determine whether its
proposed fees meet the Exchange Act’s
requirements.153 One commenter stated
that, in the absence of cost data, the
Commission lacks an effective basis for
evaluating whether proposed market
data fees are fair or reasonable.154 In
addition, these commenters suggested
that because the Commission concluded
that a cost-based analysis was required
in the context of a fee dispute between
Nasdaq and the CTA, the Commission
should require the same cost-based
analysis for exchanges’ market data
fees.155 Another commenter believed
that the exchanges’ use of market data
fees to fund rebates to order entry firms
suggested that market data pricing is
‘‘neither competitive nor efficient.’’ 156
NetCoalition and SIFMA asserted that
the Draft Order would in effect be an
amendment of Rule 19b–4 and thus
149 Evans
Report at 13–16.
V at 7; SIFMA IX at 20.
151 SIFMA IX at 3; Evans Report at 5–6; SLCG
Study at 12.
152 Evans Report at 5–6.
153 NetCoalition V at 15–18; SIFMA IX at 4.
154 SIFMA IX at 4. Similarly, the SLCG Study
maintained that it is not possible to assess the
extent of NYSE Arca’s market power in establishing
fees for Arca Book data without information
concerning the costs of collecting and distributing
the data. Accordingly, the SLCG Study asserted that
the Commission could not reasonably conclude that
the NYSE was subject to competitive forces in
establishing the proposed Arca Book data fees.
SLCG Study at 31–32.
155 NetCoalition V at 15–18; SIFMA IX at 11–13.
156 STA Letter at 3.
150 NetCoalition
E:\FR\FM\09DEN1.SGM
09DEN1
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 237 / Tuesday, December 9, 2008 / Notices
would constitute agency rulemaking
that must be published for notice and
comment under the Administrative
Procedures Act.157 Another commenter
believed that greater transparency prior
to the publication of the Draft Order
would have allowed the Commission to
gather additional data.158
Five commenters, including NYSE
Arca, supported issuance of the Draft
Order.159 They generally agreed that
significant competitive forces operate in
the distribution of non-core data and
will constrain the exchanges in setting
the terms for such data. For example,
ISE agreed with the Draft Order’s
analysis of the relationship between
non-core data and attracting order flow,
noting that it views its proprietary
depth-of-book options data service as an
important means to advertise the prices
available on the ISE and to attract orders
to ISE.160 It currently offers the service
free of charge, but only 15% of its
members have chosen to subscribe to
the service.161
Similarly, Thomson Reuters believed
that the Commission’s Draft Order
correctly analyzed the competitive
forces applicable to the establishment of
fees for depth-of-book data.162 In
particular, the commenter agreed that,
in light of the competitive market for
order flow and trade execution, an
exchange would have strong
competitive reasons to price its depthof-book data so that the data would be
distributed widely to those most likely
to use it to trade.163 The commenter also
believed that ‘‘the application of market
forces to the consolidation and
distribution of market data is generally
preferable to increased government
supervision of the process of setting fees
for and licensing subscribers to market
data.’’ 164
The Ordover/Bamberger Statement
noted that unnecessary regulation of a
market characterized by effective
competition can distort the operation of
the market and produce ‘‘unforeseen
and unintended consequences,’’ and
that ‘‘cost-based regulation can create
significant inefficiencies and
distortions.’’ 165 It identified market data
and trade execution services as an
example of ‘‘joint products’’ with ‘‘joint
costs’’ that determine a trading
platform’s total return.166 The Statement
noted that competition among trading
platforms could be expected to limit the
return each platform earned from the
sale of joint products, although different
platforms could select different pricing
strategies and means of recovering
costs.167
Another commenter believed that
NYSE Arca’s proprietary data would
benefit retail investors and that the
Exchange’s proposed fees are fair
compensation for its data.168 Noting that
U.S. exchanges face increasing
competition from foreign markets, dark
pools, and electronic communications
networks, the commenter stated that it
is important for U.S. exchanges to have
the ability to offer real-time market
data.169 Finally, NYSE Arca believed
that the Commission’s standard would
spur innovation and allow markets to
introduce new market data products
more quickly, thereby enhancing the
competitiveness of the U.S. securities
markets.170
VI. Discussion
The Commission finds that the
Proposal is consistent with the
requirements of the Exchange Act and
the rules and regulations thereunder
applicable to a national securities
exchange. In particular, it is consistent
with section 6(b)(4) of the Exchange
Act,171 which requires that the rules of
a national securities exchange provide
for the equitable allocation of reasonable
dues, fees, and other charges among its
members and issuers and other parties
using its facilities, and section 6(b)(5) of
the Exchange Act,172 which requires,
among other things, that the rules of a
national securities exchange be
designed to promote just and equitable
principles of trade, to remove
impediments to and perfect the
mechanism of a free and open market
and a national market system and, in
general, to protect investors and the
public interest, and not be designed to
permit unfair discrimination between
customers, issuers, brokers, or dealers.
The Commission also finds that the
Proposal is consistent with the
provisions of section 6(b)(8) of the
Exchange Act,173 which requires that
166 Id.
at 3–4.
at 4. See also id. at 3 n. 4 (‘‘It is widely
accepted that there is no meaningful way to allocate
‘common costs’ across different joint products. For
this reason, ‘cost-based’ regulation of the price of
market data would require inherently arbitrary cost
allocations.’’).
168 Rutherford Comment.
169 Id.
170 NYSE Arca IV at 2.
171 15 U.S.C. 78f(b)(4).
172 15 U.S.C. 78f(b)(5).
173 15 U.S.C. 78f(b)(8).
167 Id.
157 NetCoalition
V at 18; SIFMA IX at 16.
of Commerce II at 2.
159 ISE II, Nasdaq II, NYSE Arca IV, Rutherford
Comment, and Thomson Reuters Letter.
160 ISE II at 2.
161 Id.
162 Thomson Reuters Letter at 3.
163 Id.
164 Id. at 2.
165 Ordover/Bamberger Statement at 2, 3 n. 4.
pwalker on PROD1PC71 with NOTICES
158 Chamber
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:00 Dec 08, 2008
Jkt 217001
PO 00000
Frm 00097
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
74779
the rules of an exchange not impose any
burden on competition not necessary or
appropriate in furtherance of the
purposes of the Exchange Act. Finally,
the Commission finds that the Proposal
is consistent with Rule 603(a) of
Regulation NMS,174 adopted under
section 11A(c)(1) of the Exchange Act,
which requires an exclusive processor
that distributes information with respect
to quotations for or transactions in an
NMS stock to do so on terms that are
fair and reasonable and that are not
unreasonably discriminatory.175
A. Commission Review of Proposals for
Distributing Non-Core Data
The standards in section 6 of the
Exchange Act and Rule 603 of
Regulation NMS do not differentiate
between types of data and therefore
apply to exchange proposals to
distribute both core data and non-core
data. Core data is the best-priced
quotations and comprehensive last sale
reports of all markets that the
Commission, pursuant to Rule 603(b),
requires a central processor to
consolidate and distribute to the public
pursuant to joint-SRO plans.176 In
contrast, individual exchanges and
other market participants distribute
non-core data voluntarily. As discussed
further below, the mandatory nature of
the core data disclosure regime leaves
little room for competitive forces to
determine products and fees. Non-core
data products and their fees are, by
contrast, much more sensitive to
competitive forces. For example, the
Commission does not believe that
broker-dealers are required to purchase
depth-of-book order data, including the
NYSE Arca data, to meet their duty of
best execution.177 The Commission
therefore is able to use competitive
forces in its determination of whether
an exchange’s proposal to distribute
non-core data meets the standards of
section 6 and Rule 603.
174 17
CFR 242.603(a).
Arca is an exclusive processor of the
NYSE Arca Data under Section 3(a)(22)(B) of the
Exchange Act, 15 U.S.C. 78c(a)(22)(B), which
defines an exclusive processor as, among other
things, an exchange that distributes information
with respect to quotations or transactions on an
exclusive basis on its own behalf.
176 See Rule 603(b) of Regulation NMS (‘‘Every
national securities exchange on which an NMS
stock is traded and national securities association
shall act jointly pursuant to one or more effective
national market system plans to disseminate
consolidated information, including a national best
bid and national best offer, on quotations for and
transactions in NMS stocks. Such plan or plans
shall provide for the dissemination of all
consolidated information for an individual NMS
stock through a single plan processor.’’)
177 See notes 259–266 below and accompanying
text.
175 NYSE
E:\FR\FM\09DEN1.SGM
09DEN1
74780
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 237 / Tuesday, December 9, 2008 / Notices
pwalker on PROD1PC71 with NOTICES
The requirements for distributing core
data to the public were first established
in the 1970s as part of the creation of
the national market system for equity
securities.178 Although Congress
intended to rely on competitive forces to
the greatest extent possible to shape the
national market system, it also granted
the Commission full rulemaking
authority in the Exchange Act to achieve
the goal of providing investors with a
central source of consolidated market
information.179
Pursuant to this Exchange Act
authority, the Commission has required
the SROs to participate in three jointindustry plans (‘‘Plans’’) pursuant to
which core data is distributed to the
public.180 The Plans establish three
separate networks to disseminate core
data for NMS stocks: (1) Network A for
securities primarily listed on the NYSE;
(2) Network C for securities primarily
listed on Nasdaq; and (3) Network B for
securities primarily listed on exchanges
other than the NYSE and Nasdaq. For
each security, the data includes: (1) A
national best bid and offer (‘‘NBBO’’)
with prices, sizes, and market center
identifications; (2) the best bids and
offers from each SRO that include
prices, sizes, and market center
identifications; and (3) last sale reports
from each SRO. The three Networks
establish fees for this core data, which
must be filed for Commission
approval.181 The Networks collect the
applicable fees and, after deduction of
Network expenses, distribute the
remaining revenues to their individual
SRO participants.
The Plans promote the wide
availability of core market data.182 For
each of the more than 7000 NMS stocks,
quotations and trades are continuously
collected from many different trading
centers and then disseminated to the
public by the central processor for a
Network in a consolidated stream of
data. As a result, investors have access
to a reliable source of information for
the best prices in NMS stocks.
Commission rules long have required
broker-dealers and data vendors, if they
provide any data to customers, to also
provide core data to investors in certain
contexts, such as trading and orderrouting.183 In addition, compliance with
the trade-through requirements of Rule
611 of Regulation NMS 184 necessitates
obtaining core quotation data because it
includes all the quotations that are
entitled to protection against tradethroughs.185
For many years, the core data
distributed through the Networks
overwhelmingly dominated the field of
equity market data in the U.S. With the
initiation of decimal trading in 2001,
however, the value to market
participants of non-core data,
particularly depth-of-book order data,
increased.186 An exchange’s depth-ofbook order data includes displayed
trading interest at prices inferior to the
best-priced quotations that exchanges
are required to provide for distribution
in the core data feeds. Prior to decimal
trading, significant size accumulated at
the best-priced quotes because the
minimum spread between the national
best bid and the national best offer was
1⁄16th, or 6.25 cents. When the minimum
inside spread was reduced to one cent,
the size displayed at the best quotes
decreased substantially, while the size
displayed at the various one-cent price
points away from the inside quotes
became a more useful tool to assess
market depth.
In 2005, the Commission adopted new
rules that, among other things,
addressed market data.187 Some
commenters on the rule proposals
178 These requirements are discussed in detail in
section III of the Concept Release on Market
Information, 64 FR at 70618–70623.
179 H.R. Rep. No. 94–229, 94th Cong., 1st Sess. 92
(1975) (‘‘Conference Report’’).
180 The three joint-industry plans, approved by
the Commission, are: (1) The CTA Plan, which is
operated by the Consolidated Tape Association and
disseminates transaction information for securities
primarily listed on an exchange other than Nasdaq;
(2) the CQ Plan, which disseminates consolidated
quotation information for securities primarily listed
on an exchange other than Nasdaq; and (3) the
Nasdaq UTP Plan, which disseminates consolidated
transaction and quotation information for securities
primarily listed on Nasdaq. The CTA Plan and CQ
Plan are available at https://www.nysedata.com. The
Nasdaq UTP Plan is available at https://
www.utpdata.com.
181 Rule 608(b)(1) of Regulation NMS, 17 CFR
242.608(b)(1).
182 The Plan provisions for distributing quotation
and transaction information are discussed in detail
in section II of the Concept Release on Market
Information, 64 FR at 70615–70618.
183 Rule 603(c) of Regulation NMS, 17 CFR
242.603(c).
184 17 CFR 242.611.
185 Rule 600(b)(57)(iii) of Regulation NMS, 17
CFR 242.600(b)(57)(iii) (definition of ‘‘protected
bid’’ and ‘‘protected offer’’ limited to the best bids
and best offers of SROs). The Commission decided
not to adopt a proposal which would have
protected depth-of-book quotations against tradethroughs if the market displaying such quotations
voluntarily disseminated them in the consolidated
quotation stream. Regulation NMS Release, 70 FR
at 37529.
186 Commenters on the Draft Order cited
statements by the Commission’s Chairman in 2002
as indicating competitive forces do not apply to
non-core market data. SIFMA IX at 4–5; SLCG
Study at 28–29; STA Letter at 3–4. Up to that time,
however, nearly all market data revenues had been
derived from core data. Accordingly, the
characteristics of market data revenues in the 70
years prior to 2002 shed no light on the current
state of competition for non-core data.
187 Regulation NMS Release, 70 FR at 37557–
37570.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
19:54 Dec 08, 2008
Jkt 217001
PO 00000
Frm 00098
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
recommended that the Commission
eliminate or substantially modify the
consolidation model for distributing
core data. In addressing these
comments, the Commission described
both the strengths and weaknesses of
the consolidation model. It emphasized
the benefits of the model for retail
investors, but noted the limited
opportunity for market forces to
determine the level and allocation of
fees for core data and the negative
effects on innovation by individual
markets in the provision of their data.188
The Commission ultimately decided
that the consolidation model should be
retained for core data because of the
benefit it afforded to investors, namely
‘‘helping them to assess quoted prices at
the time they place an order and to
evaluate the best execution of their
orders against such prices by obtaining
data from a single source that is highly
reliable and comprehensive.’’ 189
With respect to the distribution of
non-core data, however, the
Commission decided to maintain a
deconsolidation model that allows
greater flexibility for market forces to
determine data products and fees.190 In
particular, the Commission both
authorized the independent
dissemination of an individual market’s
or broker-dealer’s trade data, which
previously had been prohibited by
Commission rule, and streamlined the
requirements for the consolidated
display of core market data to customers
of broker-dealers and vendors.191 Most
commenters supported this approach.192
A few commenters, however,
recommended that ‘‘the Commission
should expand the consolidated display
requirement to include additional
information on depth-of-book
quotations, stating that the NBBO alone
had become less informative since
decimalization.’’ 193 Such an approach
effectively would have treated an
individual market’s depth-of-book order
data as consolidated core data and
thereby eliminated the operation of
188 Id.
at 37558.
at 37504.
190 When describing the deconsolidation model in
the context of deciding whether to propose a new
model for core data, the Commission noted that
‘‘the strength of this model is the maximum
flexibility it allows for competitive forces to
determine data products, fees, and SRO revenues.’’
Securities Exchange Act Release No. 49325
(February 26, 2004), 69 FR 11126, 11177 (March 9,
2004). As discussed in the text, the Commission
decided to retain the consolidation model, rather
than proposing a new deconsolidation model, for
core data.
191 See Regulation NMS Release, 70 FR at 37566–
37567 (addressing differences in distribution
standards between core data and non-core data).
192 Id.
193 Id. at 37567 (citation omitted).
189 Id.
E:\FR\FM\09DEN1.SGM
09DEN1
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 237 / Tuesday, December 9, 2008 / Notices
competitive forces on depth-of-book
order data. The Commission did not
adopt this recommendation, but instead
decided to:
In addition, Congress explicitly noted
the importance of relying on
competition in overseeing the activities
of the SROs:
allow market forces, rather than regulatory
requirements, to determine what, if any,
additional quotations outside the NBBO are
displayed to investors. Investors who need
the BBOs of each SRO, as well as more
comprehensive depth-of-book information,
will be able to obtain such data from markets
or third party vendors.194
S. 249 would give the SEC broad authority
not only to oversee the general development
of a national market system but also to insure
that the ancillary programs of the selfregulatory organizations and their affiliates
are consistent with the best interests of the
securities industry and the investing public
* * *. This is not to suggest that under S.
249 the SEC would have either the
responsibility or the power to operate as an
‘economic czar’ for the development of a
national market system. Quite the contrary,
for a fundamental premise of the bill is that
the initiative for the development of the
facilities of a national market system must
come from private interests and will depend
on the vigor of competition within the
securities industry as broadly defined.198
Some commenters on the Proposal
and the Petition recommended
fundamental changes in the regulatory
treatment of non-core data in general
and depth-of-book quotations in
particular.195 The Commission,
however, considered this issue in 2005
and continues to hold the views just
described. It does not believe that
circumstances have changed
significantly since 2005 and will
continue to apply a primarily marketbased approach for assessing whether
exchange proposals to distribute noncore data meet the applicable statutory
standards.
The Exchange Act and its legislative
history strongly support the
Commission’s reliance on competition,
whenever possible, in meeting its
regulatory responsibilities for
overseeing the SROs and the national
market system. Indeed, competition
among multiple markets and market
participants trading the same products
is the hallmark of the national market
system.196 A national market ‘‘system’’
can be contrasted with a single
monopoly market that overwhelmingly
dominates trading its listed products.
Congress repeatedly emphasized the
benefits of competition among markets
in protecting investors and promoting
the public interest. When directing the
Commission to facilitate the
establishment of a national market
system, for example, Congress
emphasized the importance of allowing
competitive forces to work:
pwalker on PROD1PC71 with NOTICES
In 1936, this Committee pointed out that a
major responsibility of the SEC in the
administration of the securities laws is to
‘‘create a fair field of competition.’’ This
responsibility continues today. The bill
would more clearly identify this
responsibility and clarify and strengthen the
SEC’s authority to carry it out. The objective
would be to enhance competition and to
allow economic forces, interacting within a
fair regulatory field, to arrive at appropriate
variations in practices and services.197
194 Id.
(citations omitted) (emphasis added).
section III.A.4 above.
196 See, e.g., Exchange Act Section
11A(a)(1)(C)(ii).
197 S. Rep. No. 94–75, 94th Cong., 1st Sess. 8
(1975) (‘‘Senate Report’’).
195 See
VerDate Aug<31>2005
19:54 Dec 08, 2008
Jkt 217001
With respect to market information,
Congress again expressed its preference
for the Commission to rely on
competition, but noted the possibility
that competition might not be sufficient
in the specific context of core data—the
central facilities for the required
distribution of consolidated data to the
public:
It is the intent of the conferees that the
national market system evolve through the
interplay of competitive forces as
unnecessary regulatory restrictions are
removed. The conferees expect, however,
that in those situations where competition
may not be sufficient, such as in the creation
of a composite quotation system or a
consolidated transactional reporting system,
the Commission will use the powers granted
to it in this bill to act promptly and
effectively to insure that the essential
mechanisms of an integrated secondary
trading system are put into effect as rapidly
as possible.199
The Commission’s approach to core
data and non-core data follows this
Congressional intent exactly. With
respect to the systems for the required
distribution of consolidated core data,
the Commission retained a regulatory
approach that uses joint-industry plans
and a central processor designed to
assure access to the best quotations and
most recent last sale information that is
so vital to investors. With respect to
non-core data, in contrast, the
Commission has maintained a marketbased approach that leaves a much
fuller opportunity for competitive forces
to work.
This market-based approach to noncore data has two parts. The first is to
ask whether the exchange was subject to
significant competitive forces in setting
the terms of its proposal for non-core
data, including the level of any fees. If
198 Senate
Report at 12.
Report at 92 (emphasis added).
199 Conference
PO 00000
Frm 00099
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
74781
an exchange was subject to significant
competitive forces in setting the terms
of a proposal, the Commission will
approve the proposal unless it
determines that there is a substantial
countervailing basis to find that the
terms nevertheless fail to meet an
applicable requirement of the Exchange
Act or the rules thereunder. If, however,
the exchange was not subject to
significant competitive forces in setting
the terms of a proposal for non-core
data, the Commission will require the
exchange to provide a substantial basis,
other than competitive forces, in its
proposed rule change demonstrating
that the terms of the proposal are
equitable, fair, reasonable, and not
unreasonably discriminatory.
As discussed above, the Commission
believes that, when possible, reliance on
competitive forces is the most
appropriate and effective means to
assess whether terms for the distribution
of non-core data are equitable, fair and
reasonable, and not unreasonably
discriminatory. If competitive forces are
operative, the self-interest of the
exchanges themselves will work
powerfully to constrain unreasonable or
unfair behavior. As discussed further
below, when an exchange is subject to
competitive forces in its distribution of
non-core data, many market participants
would be unlikely to purchase the
exchange’s data products if it sets fees
that are inequitable, unfair,
unreasonable, or unreasonably
discriminatory. As a result, competitive
forces generally will constrain an
exchange in setting fees for non-core
data because it should recognize that its
own profits will suffer if it attempts to
act unreasonably or unfairly. For
example, an exchange’s attempt to
impose unreasonably or unfairly
discriminatory fees on a certain category
of customers would likely be counterproductive for the exchange because, in
a competitive environment, such
customers generally would be able to
respond by using alternatives to the
exchange’s data.200 The Commission
therefore believes that the existence of
significant competition provides a
substantial basis for finding that the
200 See, e.g., Richard Posner, Economic Analysis
of Law § 9.1 (5th ed. 1998) (discussing the theory
of monopolies and pricing). See also U.S. Dep’t of
Justice & Fed’l Trade Comm’n, Horizontal Merger
Guidelines § 1.11 (1992), as revised (1997) (‘‘DOJ
Merger Guidelines’’) (explaining the importance of
alternative products in evaluating the presence of
competition and defining markets and market
power). Courts frequently refer to the Department
of Justice and Federal Trade Commission merger
guidelines to define product markets and evaluate
market power. See, e.g., FTC v. Whole Foods
Market, Inc., 502 F. Supp. 2d 1 (D.D.C. 2007); FTC
v. Arch Coal, Inc., 329 F. Supp. 2d 109 (D.D.C.
2004).
E:\FR\FM\09DEN1.SGM
09DEN1
74782
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 237 / Tuesday, December 9, 2008 / Notices
terms of an exchange’s fee proposal are
equitable, fair, reasonable, and not
unreasonably or unfairly discriminatory.
Even when competitive forces are
operative, however, the Commission
will continue to review exchange
proposals for distributing non-core data
to assess whether there is a substantial
countervailing basis for determining
that a proposal is inconsistent with the
Exchange Act.201 For example, an
exchange proposal that seeks to penalize
market participants for trading in
markets other than the proposing
exchange would present a substantial
countervailing basis for finding
unreasonable and unfair discrimination
and likely would prevent the
Commission from approving an
exchange proposal.202 In the absence of
such a substantial countervailing basis
for finding that a proposal failed to meet
the applicable statutory standards, the
Commission would approve the
exchange proposal as consistent with
the Exchange Act and rules applicable
to the exchange.
order flow from market participants;
and (2) the availability to market
participants of alternatives to
purchasing the ArcaBook data.
pwalker on PROD1PC71 with NOTICES
B. Review of Competitive Forces
Applicable to NYSE Arca
The terms of an exchange’s proposed
rule change to distribute market data for
which it is an exclusive processor must,
among other things, provide for an
equitable allocation of reasonable fees
under section 6(b)(4), not be designed to
permit unfair discrimination under
section 6(b)(5), be fair and reasonable
under Rule 603(a)(1), and not be
unreasonably discriminatory under Rule
603(a)(2). Because NYSE Arca is
proposing to distribute non-core data,
the Commission reviewed the terms of
the Proposal under the market-based
approach described above. The first
question is whether NYSE Arca was
subject to significant competitive forces
in setting the terms of the Proposal.
At least two broad types of significant
competitive forces applied to NYSE
Arca in setting the terms of its Proposal
to distribute the ArcaBook data: (1)
NYSE Arca’s compelling need to attract
1. Competition for Order Flow
Attracting order flow is the core
competitive concern of any equity
exchange—it is the ‘‘without which,
not’’ of an exchange’s competitive
success. If an exchange cannot attract
orders, it will not be able to execute
transactions. If it cannot execute
transactions, it will not generate
transaction revenue. If an exchange
cannot attract orders or execute
transactions, it will not have market
data to distribute, for a fee or otherwise,
and will not earn market data
revenue.203
In the U.S. national market system,
buyers and sellers of securities, and the
broker-dealers that act as their orderrouting agents, have a wide range of
choices of where to route orders for
execution. They include, of course, any
of the nine national securities exchanges
that currently trade equities, but also
include a wide variety of non-exchange
trading venues: (1) Electronic
communication networks (‘‘ECNs’’) that
display their quotes directly in the core
data stream by participating in FINRA’s
Alternative Display Facility (‘‘ADF’’) or
displaying their quotations through an
exchange; (2) alternative trading systems
(‘‘ATSs’’) that offer a wide variety of
order execution strategies, including
block crossing services for institutions
that wish to trade anonymously in large
size and midpoint matching services for
the execution of smaller orders; and (3)
securities firms that primarily trade as
principal with their customer order
flow.
NYSE Arca must compete with all of
these different trading venues to attract
order flow, and the competition is
fierce. For example, in its response to
the commenters, NYSE Arca notes that
its share of trading in 2005 was 3.6% in
Network A stocks, 23% in Network C
stocks, and 30% in Network B stocks.204
201 See Exchange Act Section 19(b)(2) (‘‘The
Commission shall approve a proposed rule change
of a self-regulatory organization if it finds that such
proposed rule change is consistent with the
requirements of this title and the rules and
regulations thereunder applicable to such
organization. The Commission shall disapprove a
proposed rule change of a self-regulatory
organization if it does not make such finding.’’).
202 Cf. Regulation NMS Release, 70 FR at 37540
(in discussion of market access fees under Rule 610
of Regulation NMS, the Commission noted that
‘‘any attempt by an SRO to charge differential fees
based on the non-member status of the person
obtaining indirect access to quotations, such as
whether it is a competing market maker, would
violate the anti-discrimination standard of Rule
610.’’).
203 See Exchange Market Data Coalition Letter at
3 (‘‘The end product of these efforts—the listings,
the members, the trading facilities, the regulation—
is market data. Market data is the totality of the
information assets that each Exchange creates by
attracting order flow.’’).
204 NYSE Arca Response III at 18 n. 44. The NYSE
and NYSE Arca are wholly-owned subsidiaries of
NYSE Group, Inc. One commenter stated that the
NYSE had ‘‘combined Arca’s liquidity pool with its
own,’’ and that ‘‘the networking effect of the NYSE
Group’s combined pool of liquidity’’ had resulted
in ‘‘greater market power over its pricing for market
data.’’ SIFMA IV at 8 (emphasis in original). In fact,
the NYSE and NYSE Arca liquidity pools have not
been combined. The two exchanges operate as
separate trading centers with separate limit order
books, and each distributes its depth-of-book order
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:00 Dec 08, 2008
Jkt 217001
PO 00000
Frm 00100
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
More recently during June 2008, NYSE
Arca share volume was 14.0% in
Network A stocks, 16.1% in Network C
stocks, and 26.7% in Network B stocks,
adding up to 16.5% of total U.S. market
volume.205
Given the competitive pressures that
currently characterize the U.S. equity
markets, no exchange can afford to take
its market share percentages for
granted—they can change significantly
over time, either up or down.206 Even
the most dominant exchanges are
subject to severe pressure in the current
competitive environment. For example,
the NYSE’s reported market share of
trading in NYSE-listed stocks declined
from 79.1% in January 2005 to 30.6% in
June 2008.207 In addition, a nonexchange entrant to equity trading—the
BATS ECN—has succeeded in capturing
7.4% of trading in NYSE-listed stocks
and 10.3% of trading in Nasdaq-listed
stocks.208 Another ECN—Direct Edge—
has a matched market share of 3.7% in
NYSE-listed stocks and 5.8% in Nasdaqlisted stocks.209 Moreover, nearly all
venues now offer trading in all U.S.listed equities, no matter the particular
exchange on which a stock is listed or
on which the most trading occurs. As a
result, many trading venues stand ready
to provide an immediately accessible
order-routing alternative for brokerdealers and investors if an exchange
data separately for separate fees. In analyzing the
competitive position of NYSE Arca for purposes of
distributing such data, the Commission has
considered NYSE Arca both as a trading center
separate from the NYSE and as part of the same
corporate group as NYSE. It finds that in both
contexts NYSE Arca was subject to significant
competitive forces in setting the terms for the
ArcaBook data. See section VI.C below for a
discussion of the regulatory requirements
applicable to individual national securities
exchanges operating separate liquidity pools.
205 Source: ArcaVision (available at https://
www.arcavision.com); see also NYSE Arca
Response III at 18 (‘‘NYSE Arca does not maintain
a dominant share of the market in any of the three
networks.’’).
206 See Exchange Market Data Coalition Letter at
4 (‘‘Exchanges compete not only with one another,
but also with broker dealers that match customer
orders within their own systems and also with a
proliferation of alternative trading systems
(‘‘ATSs’’) and electronic communications networks
(‘‘ECNs’’) that the Commission has also nurtured
and authorized to execute trades in any listed issue.
As a result, market share of trading fluctuates
among execution facilities based upon their ability
to service the end customer.’’).
207 Source: ArcaVision (available at https://
www.arcavision.com).
208 Lehman Brothers, Inc., Equity Research,
‘‘Exchanges June Volume Analysis’’ at 2 (July 2,
2008) (‘‘Lehman Trading Volume Analysis’’) at 2.
The Commission recently granted an application by
BATS Exchange, Inc. for registration as a national
securities exchange. Securities Exchange Act
Release No. 58375 (Aug. 18, 2008), 73 FR 49498
(Aug. 21, 2008).
209 Lehman Trading Volume Analysis at 2.
E:\FR\FM\09DEN1.SGM
09DEN1
74783
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 237 / Tuesday, December 9, 2008 / Notices
attempts to act unreasonably in setting
the terms for its services.
Table 1 below provides a useful
recent snapshot of the state of
competition in the U.S. equity markets
in the month of June 2008: 210
TABLE 1—REPORTED SHARE VOLUME IN U.S.-LISTED EQUITIES DURING JUNE 2008
[Percent]
Trading venue
All stocks
All Non-Exchange ........................................................................................................................
Nasdaq .........................................................................................................................................
NYSE ...........................................................................................................................................
NYSE Arca ...................................................................................................................................
National Stock Exchange ............................................................................................................
International Stock Exchange ......................................................................................................
American Stock Exchange ..........................................................................................................
Chicago Stock Exchange ............................................................................................................
CBOE Stock Exchange ...............................................................................................................
Philadelphia Stock Exchange ......................................................................................................
31.9
30.4
17.4
16.5
1.8
0.9
0.5
0.4
0.1
0.1
NYSE-listed
28.9
23.0
30.6
14.0
1.4
1.4
0.0
0.5
0.1
0.1
Nasdaq-listed
38.0
42.7
0.0
16.1
2.4
0.2
0.0
0.3
0.2
0.1
pwalker on PROD1PC71 with NOTICES
Perhaps the most notable item of
information from Table 1 is that nonexchange trading venues collectively
have a larger share of trading than any
single exchange. Much of this volume is
attributable to ECNs such as BATS and
Direct Edge, noted above. In addition,
the proliferation of non-exchange pools
of liquidity has been a significant
development in the U.S. equity
markets.211 Broker-dealers often check
the liquidity available in these pools as
a first choice prior to routing orders to
an exchange. In sum, no exchange
possesses a monopoly, regulatory or
otherwise, in the execution of order
flow from broker-dealers.
The market share percentages in Table
1 strongly indicate that NYSE Arca must
compete vigorously for order flow to
maintain its share of trading volume. As
discussed below, this compelling need
to attract order flow imposes significant
pressure on NYSE Arca to act
reasonably in setting its fees for depthof-book order data, particularly given
that the market participants that must
pay such fees often will be the same
market participants from whom NYSE
Arca must attract order flow.212 These
market participants particularly include
the large broker-dealer firms that control
the handling of a large volume of
customer and proprietary order flow.
Given the portability of order flow from
one trading venue to another, any
exchange that sought to charge
unreasonably high data fees would risk
alienating many of the same customers
on whose orders it depends for
competitive survival.213
Some commenters asserted that an
exchange’s distribution of depth-of-book
order data is not affected by its need to
attract order flow.214 Attracting order
flow and distributing market data,
however, are in fact two sides of the
same coin and cannot be separated.215
Moreover, the relation between
attracting order flow and distributing
market data operates in both directions.
An exchange’s ability to attract order
flow determines whether it has market
data to distribute, while the exchange’s
distribution of market data significantly
affects its ability to attract order flow.216
For example, orders can be divided
into two broad types—those that seek to
offer liquidity to the market at a
particular price (non-marketable orders)
and those that seek an immediate
execution by taking the offered liquidity
(marketable orders). The wide
distribution of an exchange’s market
data, including depth-of-book order
data, to many market participants is an
important factor in attracting both types
of orders. Depth-of-book order data
consists of non-marketable orders that a
prospective buyer or seller has chosen
to display. The primary reason for a
prospective buyer or seller to display its
trading interest at a particular price, and
thereby offer a free option to all market
participants at that price, is to attract
contra trading interest and a fast
execution. The extent to which a
displayed non-marketable order attracts
contra interest will depend greatly on
the wide distribution of the displayed
order to many market participants. If
only a limited number of market
participants receive an exchange’s
depth-of-book order data, it reduces the
chance of an execution for those who
display non-marketable orders on that
exchange. Limited distribution of
displayed orders thereby reduces the
ability of the exchange to attract such
orders. Moreover, by failing to secure
wide distribution of its displayed
orders, the exchange will reduce its
ability to attract marketable orders
seeking to take the displayed liquidity.
In other words, limited distribution of
depth-of-book order data will limit an
210 Source: ArcaVision (available at https://
www.arcavision.com).
211 See, e.g., NYSE Arca Response III at 17 (‘‘If the
brokerage firm is unable to internalize the trade,
typically, it next takes the order to dark pools,
crossing networks, ECNs, alternative trading
systems, or other non-traditional execution facilities
to search for an execution.’’); https://
www.advancedtrading.com/directories/darkpool
(directory of more than 20 non-exchange pools of
liquidity that are classified as ‘‘independent,’’
‘‘broker-dealer-owned,’’ and ‘‘consortium-owned.’’).
212 See, e.g., Exchange Market Data Coalition
Letter at 4 (‘‘It is in the Exchange’s best interest to
provide proprietary information to investors to
further their business objectives, and each Exchange
chooses how best to do that.’’); Nasdaq Letter at 9
(‘‘Like the market for electronic executions, the
related market for proprietary data is also
influenced by the equity investments of major
financial institutions in one or more exchanges
* * *. Equity investors control substantial order
flow and transaction reports that are the essential
ingredients of successful proprietary data products.
Equity investors also can enable exchanges to
develop competitive proprietary products * * *.’’).
213 See NYSE Arca Response III at 16 (‘‘Markets
compete with one another by seeking to maximize
the amount of order flow that they attract. The
markets base competition for order flow on such
things as technology, customer service, transaction
costs, ease of access, liquidity and transparency. In
recent months, significant changes in market share,
the rush to establish trade-reporting facilities for the
reporting of off-exchange trades, frequent changes
in transaction fees and new market data proposals
have provided evidence of the intensity of the
competition for order flow.’’).
214 See section III.A.5 above.
215 See, e.g., Larry Harris, Trading and Exchanges,
Market Microstructure for Practitioners 99 (2003)
(noting that it would be ‘‘very difficult for
innovative trading systems to compete for order
flow’’ if the data from those trading venues were not
distributed).
216 See, e.g., NYSE Arca Response III at 13 (in
setting level of fees, one factor was ‘‘projected
losses to NYSE Arca’s business model and order
flow that might result from marketplace resistance
to Arca Book Fees’’); Report of the Advisory
Committee on Market Information: A Blueprint for
Responsible Change (September 14, 2001), Section
VII.B.1 (available at www.sec.gov) (‘‘[A] market’s
inability to widely disseminate its prices
undoubtedly will adversely impact its ability to
attract limit orders and, ultimately, all order flow.
This barrier to intermarket competition, in turn,
could decrease liquidity and innovation in the
marketplace.’’).
VerDate Aug<31>2005
19:54 Dec 08, 2008
Jkt 217001
PO 00000
Frm 00101
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
E:\FR\FM\09DEN1.SGM
09DEN1
74784
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 237 / Tuesday, December 9, 2008 / Notices
pwalker on PROD1PC71 with NOTICES
exchange’s ability to attract both nonmarketable and marketable orders.
Consequently, an exchange generally
will have strong competitive reasons to
price its depth-of-book order data so
that it will be distributed widely to
those most likely to use it to trade.217
A notable example of the close
connection between a trading venue’s
distribution of order data and its ability
to attract order flow was provided by
the Island ECN in 2002. To avoid the
application of certain regulatory
requirements, Island ceased displaying
its order book to the public in three very
active exchange-traded funds (‘‘ETFs’’)
in which it enjoyed a substantial market
share. After going ‘‘dark,’’ Island’s
market share in the three ETFs dropped
by 50%.218
This competitive pressure to attract
order flow is likely what led NYSE
Arca, and its predecessor corporation, to
distribute its depth-of-book order data
without charge in the past.219 It now has
made a business decision to begin
charging for that data, apparently
believing that it has a sufficiently
attractive data product that the benefit
obtained from increased data revenues
will outweigh the potential harm of
reduced order flow if significant
numbers of data users choose not to pay
217 See NYSE Arca Response III at 18 (‘‘If too
many market professionals reject Arca Book as too
expensive, NYSE Arca would have to reassess the
Arca Book Fees because Arca Book data provides
transparency to NYSE Arca’s market, transparency
that plays an important role in the competition for
order flow.’’). This pressure on exchanges to
distribute their order data widely is heightened for
those exchanges that have converted from memberowned, not-for profit entities to shareholder-owned,
for-profit companies. For-profit exchanges are more
likely to place greater importance on distributing
market information widely than on limiting such
information for the use of their members.
218 See Terrence Hendershott and Charles. M.
Jones, ‘‘Island Goes Dark: Transparency,
Fragmentation, and Regulation,’’ 18 The Review of
Financial Studies (No. 3) 743, 756 (2005); see also
Nasdaq Letter at 7 (‘‘[T]he market for proprietary
data products is currently competitive and
inherently contestable because there is fierce
competition for the inputs necessary to the creation
of proprietary data and strict pricing discipline for
the proprietary data products themselves.’’). In
contrast to the Island example, and as noted in the
Nasdaq Letter at 9, an element of the BATS ECN’s
business strategy over the last two years in gaining
order flow has been to provide its order data to
customers free of charge. See BATS Trading,
Newsletter (July 2007) (available at https://
www.batstrading.com/newsletters/
0707Newsletter.pdf) (‘‘BATS has chosen not to
charge for many of the things for which our
competitors charge. * * * More importantly, our
market data is free. Why would a market charge its
participants for the data they send to that market?
Feel free to pose this same question to our
competitors.’’).
219 Cf. NYSE Arca Response III at 4 (‘‘Several
years ago, certain [ECNs] began to make their realtime quotes available for free in order to gain
visibility in the market place.’’).
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:00 Dec 08, 2008
Jkt 217001
the fee.220 Commenters concede that
NYSE Arca is entitled to charge a fee for
its depth-of-book order data,221 but
claim that the fee chosen by NYSE Arca
is unaffected by its need to attract order
flow.222 The Commission disagrees and
notes that NYSE Arca, in setting the fee,
acknowledged that it needed to balance
its desire for market data revenues with
the potential damage that a high fee
would do to its ability to attract order
flow.223
2. Availability of Alternatives to
ArcaBook Data
In addition to the need to attract order
flow, the availability of alternatives to
an exchange’s depth-of-book order data
significantly affects the terms on which
an exchange distributes such data.224
The primary use of depth-of-book order
data is to assess the depth of the market
for a stock beyond that which is shown
by the best-priced quotations that are
distributed in core data. Institutional
investors that need to trade in large size
typically seek to assess market depth
beyond the best prices, in contrast to
retail investors who generally can
expect to receive the best price or better
when they trade in smaller sizes.225
In setting the fees for its depth-ofbook order data, an exchange must
consider the extent to which
sophisticated traders would choose one
or more alternatives instead of
purchasing the exchange’s data.226 Of
220 NYSE Arca Response I at 4 (‘‘[F]ees will
enable the Exchange to further diversify its revenue
to compete with its rivals. The Exchange believes
that its business has reached the point where its
customers are willing to pay for the value of the
Exchange’s information.’’).
221 See, e.g., Petition at 9; SIFMA I at 7.
222 See notes 147–149 above and accompanying
text.
223 NYSE Arca Response III at 13 (in setting the
level of fees for ArcaBook data, NYSE Arca
considered ‘‘projected losses to NYSE Arca’s
business model and order flow that might result
from marketplace resistance to’’ the fees).
224 See NYSE Arca Response III at 13 (in setting
fees for ArcaBook data, NYSE Arca considered ‘‘the
fact that Arca Book is primarily a product for
market professionals, who have access to other
sources of market data and who will purchase Arca
Book only if they determine that the perceived
benefits outweigh the cost’’); see also the authorities
cited in note 200 above. In considering antitrust
issues, courts have recognized the value of
competition in producing lower prices. See, e.g.,
Leegin Creative Leather Products v. PSKS, Inc., 127
S. Ct. 2705 (2007); Atlanta Richfield Co. v. United
States Petroleum Co., 495 U.S. 328 (1990);
Matsushita Elec. Indus. Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp.,
475 U.S. 574 (1986); State Oil Co. v. Khan, 522 U.S.
3 (1997); Northern Pacific Railway Co. v. U.S., 356
U.S. 1 (1958).
225 The market information needs of retail
investor are discussed at notes 229–336 below and
accompanying text.
226 See NYSE Arca Response III at 17 (‘‘As a result
of all of the choices and discretion that are available
to brokers, the displayed depth-of-book data of one
PO 00000
Frm 00102
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
course, the most basic source of
information concerning the depth
generally available at an exchange is the
complete record of an exchange’s
transactions that is provided in the core
data feeds. In this respect, the core data
feeds that include an exchange’s own
transaction information are a significant
alternative to the exchange’s depth-ofbook data product.
For more specific information
concerning depth, market participants
can choose among the depth-of-book
order products offered by the various
exchanges and ECNs.227 A market
participant is likely to be more
interested in other exchange and ECN
products when the exchange selling its
data has a small share of trading
volume, because the depth-of-book
order data provided by other exchanges
and ECNs will be proportionally more
important in assessing market depth. As
a result, smaller exchanges may well be
inclined to offer their data for no charge
or low fees as a means to attract order
flow. Even larger exchanges, however,
must consider the lower fees of other
exchanges in setting the fees for the
larger exchanges’ data. Significant fee
differentials could lead to shifts in order
flow that, over time, could harm a larger
exchange’s competitive position and the
value of its non-core data.
Market depth also can be assessed
with tools other than depth-of-book
order data. For example, market
participants can ‘‘ping’’ the various
markets by routing oversized marketable
limit orders to access an exchange’s
total liquidity available at an order’s
limit price or better.228 In contrast to
depth-of-book order data, pinging orders
have the important advantage of
searching out both displayed and
reserve (i.e., nondisplayed) size at all
price points within an order’s limit
price. Reserve size can represent a
substantial portion of the liquidity
available at exchanges.229 It often will
trading center does not provide a complete picture
of the full market for a security * * *. A brokerage
firm has potentially dozens of different information
sources to choose from in determining if, where,
and how to represent an order for execution.’’).
227 See Nasdaq Letter at 7–8 (‘‘The large number
of SROs, TRFs, and ECNs that currently produce
proprietary data or are currently capable of
producing it provides further pricing discipline for
proprietary data products. As shown on Exhibit A,
each SRO, TRF, ECN and BD is currently permitted
to produce proprietary data products, and many
currently do or have announced plans to do so,
including Nasdaq, NYSE, NYSEArca, and BATS.’’).
228 See Regulation NMS Release, 70 FR at 37514
(discussion of pinging orders noting that they
‘‘could as aptly be labeled ‘liquidity search’
orders’’).
229 See, e.g., NYSE Arca Response III at 17 (noting
that brokers ‘‘may elect to have NYSE Arca hold a
portion of the order as hidden interest that NYSE
E:\FR\FM\09DEN1.SGM
09DEN1
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 237 / Tuesday, December 9, 2008 / Notices
pwalker on PROD1PC71 with NOTICES
be available at prices that are better than
or equal to an exchange’s best displayed
prices, and none of this liquidity will be
discernible from an exchange’s depthof-book order data. Pinging orders
thereby give the sender an immediate
and more complete indication of the
total liquidity available at an exchange
at a particular time. Moreover,
sophisticated order routers are capable
of maintaining historical records of an
exchange’s responses to pinging orders
over time to gauge the extent of total
liquidity that generally can be expected
at an exchange. These records are a key
element used to program smart order
routing systems that implement the
algorithmic trading strategies that have
become so prevalent in recent years.230
Another alternative to depth-of-book
order data products offered by
exchanges is the threat of independent
distribution of order data by securities
firms and data vendors.231 As noted
above, one of the principal market data
reforms adopted in 2005 was to
authorize the independent distribution
of data by individual firms. To the
extent that one or more securities firms
conclude that the cost of exchange
depth-of-book order products is too high
and appreciably exceeds the cost of
aggregating and distributing such data,
they are entitled to act independently
and distribute their own order data,
with or without a fee. Indeed, a
consortium of major securities firms in
Europe has undertaken such a market
data project as part of the
implementation of the Markets in
Financial Instruments Directive
(‘‘MiFID’’) adopted by the European
Union.232 No securities statute or
Arca holds in reserve, which means that NYSE Arca
will not include the undisplayed portion of the
order as part of the Arca Book display’’); Michael
Scotti, ‘‘The Dark Likes Nasdaq,’’ Traders Magazine
(May 1, 2007) (quoting statement of Nasdaq’s
executive vice president that 15 to 18 percent of
Nasdaq’s executed liquidity is non-displayed).
230 See, e.g., https://www.advancedtrading.com/
directories/dark-algorithms (descriptions of product
offerings for ‘‘dark algorithms’’ that seek
undisplayed liquidity at multiple trading venues);
EdgeTrade, Inc., ‘‘EdgeTrade issues white paper on
market fragmentation and unprecedented liquidity
opportunities through smart order execution’’
(September 10, 2007) (available at https://
www.edgetrade.com) (‘‘EdgeTrade’s smart order
execution strategy * * * simultaneously sprays
aggregated dark pools and public markets, and then
continuously moves an order in line with shifting
liquidity until best execution is fulfilled.’’).
231 See Nasdaq Letter at 3 (‘‘Proprietary optional
data may be offered by a single broker-dealer, a
group of broker-dealers, a national securities
exchange, or a combination of broker-dealers or
exchanges, unlike consolidated data which is only
available through a consortium of SROs.’’).
232 The project—currently named ‘‘Markit
BOAT’’—distributes both quotes and trades and is
described at https://www.markit.com/information/
boat/boat-data.html. It currently charges fees of 120
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:00 Dec 08, 2008
Jkt 217001
regulation prevents U.S. firms from
undertaking an analogous project in the
U.S. for the display of depth-of-book
order data. This data could encompass
orders that are executed off of the
exchanges, as well as orders that are
submitted to exchanges for execution. If
major U.S. firms handling significant
order flow participated in the project,
the project could collect and distribute
data that covered a large proportion of
liquidity in U.S. equities.
The Commission recognizes that the
depth-of-book order data for a particular
exchange may offer advantages over the
alternatives for assessing market depth.
The relevant issue, however, is whether
the availability of these alternatives
imposes significant competitive
restraints on an exchange in setting the
terms, particularly the fees, for
distributing its depth-of-book order
data. For example, Nasdaq has a
substantial trading share in Nasdaqlisted stocks, yet only 19,000
professional users purchase Nasdaq’s
depth-of-book data product and 420,000
professional users purchase core data in
Nasdaq-listed stocks.233 A reasonable
conclusion to draw from this disparity
in the number of professional users of
consolidated core data and Nasdaq’s
non-core data is that the great majority
of professional users either believe they
do not need Nasdaq’s depth-of-book
order data or simply do not think it is
worth $76 per month to them
(approximately $3.50 per trading day)
compared to other sources of
information on market depth in Nasdaqlisted stocks. The fact that 95% of the
professional users of core data choose
not to purchase the depth-of-book order
data of a major exchange strongly
suggests that no exchange has monopoly
pricing power for its depth-of-book
order data.234
In sum, there are a variety of
alternative sources of information that
impose significant competitive
pressures on an exchange in setting fees
for its depth-of-book order data. The
Commission believes that the
availability of these alternatives, as well
euros per month per user for its quote and trade
data. See Nasdaq Letter at 9 (noting the potential
for firms to export Project BOAT technology to the
United States).
233 Nasdaq Letter at 6.
234 See id. (‘‘Empirical sales data for Nasdaq
TotalView, Nasdaq’s proprietary depth-of-book
data, demonstrate that broker-dealers do not
consider TotalView to be required for compliance
with Regulation NMS or any other regulation.
* * * [O]f the 735 broker-dealer members that trade
Nasdaq securities, only 20 or 2.7 percent spend
more than $7,000 per month on TotalView users.
Nasdaq understands that firms with more than 100
TotalView professional users generally provide
TotalView to only a small fraction of their total user
populations.’’).
PO 00000
Frm 00103
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
74785
as NYSE Arca’s compelling need to
attract order flow, imposed significant
competitive pressure on NYSE Arca to
act equitably, fairly, and reasonably in
setting the terms of the Proposal.
3. Response to Commenters on
Competition Issues
Some commenters suggested that
exchanges are not constrained by
competitive forces in distributing their
order data because Exchange Act rules
require broker-dealers to provide their
orders to an exchange, and that
exchanges therefore enjoy a regulatory
monopoly.235 As discussed above,
however, exchanges face fierce
competition in their efforts to attract
order flow. For the great majority of
orders, Exchange Act rules do not
require that they be routed to an
exchange.236 These include all
marketable orders and most nonmarketable orders. With respect to
certain types of non-marketable orders,
two Exchange Act rules can require
broker-dealers to provide such orders to
an exchange in certain circumstances,
but only when the broker-dealer chooses
to do business on the exchange. Rule
602 of Regulation NMS 237 requires
certain broker-dealers, once they have
chosen to communicate quotations on
an exchange, to provide their best
quotations to the exchange.238 Rule 604
235 See, e.g., Bloomberg Letter at 4; Financial
Services Roundtable Letter at 1; NetCoalition III at
6. Some commenters suggested that broker-dealers
were required to provide their data to exchanges for
free and then buy that data back from the
exchanges. NSX Letter at 1; SIFMA III at 12. A
broker-dealer, however, has no need to buy back its
own data, with which it is already familiar. Rather,
broker-dealers need to see data submitted by other
broker-dealers and market participants. This need is
served by the core function of a securities exchange,
which is to provide a central point for bringing buy
and sell orders together, thereby enabling the
resulting market data to be distributed to all market
participants. See, e.g., Section 3(a)(1) of the
Exchange Act, 15 U.S.C. 78c(a)(1) (‘‘exchange’’
defined as, among other things, ‘‘facilities for
bringing together purchasers and sellers of
securities’’).
236 For example, a broker-dealer commenter
asserted that exchanges enjoy a ‘‘governmentprotected monopoly’’ as exclusive processors of
their market information. Schwab Letter at 6; see
also SIFMA IV at 7 (‘‘Normal market forces cannot
be relied upon here because of the unique structure
of the market for data that the exchanges compile
from their captive broker-dealer customers and then
sell back to them.’’). As noted in Table 1 above,
non-exchange trading venues now execute more
volume in U.S.-listed equities than any single
exchange.
237 17 CFR 242.602 (previously designated as Rule
11Ac1–1).
238 Only broker-dealers that choose to participate
on an exchange as ‘‘responsible broker-dealers’’ are
required to provide their best bid and best offer to
such exchange. Rule 602(b) and Rule 600(b)(65)(i)
of Regulation NMS. Broker-dealers that participate
only in the over-the-counter (i.e., non-exchange)
E:\FR\FM\09DEN1.SGM
Continued
09DEN1
74786
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 237 / Tuesday, December 9, 2008 / Notices
pwalker on PROD1PC71 with NOTICES
of Regulation NMS 239 requires market
makers and specialists to reflect their
displayable customer limit orders in
their quotations in certain
circumstances, but provides an
exception if the order is delivered for
display through an exchange or FINRA,
or to a non-exchange ECN that delivers
the order for display through an
exchange or FINRA. Most significantly,
while these rules can require certain
orders to be displayed through an
exchange or FINRA, broker-dealers have
a great deal of flexibility in deciding
which exchange or FINRA. As discussed
above, exchanges compete vigorously to
display the non-marketable orders
handled by broker-dealers. No particular
exchange has a regulatory monopoly to
display these orders.240
Some commenters asserted that
exchanges act as monopolies in
distributing depth-of-book order data
because they are the exclusive
processors of such data, as defined in
section 3(a)(22)(B) of the Exchange Act.
Many businesses, however, are the
exclusive sources of their own products,
but this exclusivity does not mean that
a business has monopoly pricing power
when selling its product and is
impervious to competitive pressures.
The particular circumstances of the
business and its product must be
examined. As discussed above, the U.S.
exchanges are subject to significant
competitive forces in setting the terms
for their depth-of-book order products,
including the need to attract order flow
and the availability of alternatives to
their depth-of-book order products.
Consequently, NYSE Arca does not have
monopoly pricing power for ArcaBook
data merely because it meets the
statutory definition of an exclusive
processor of the data.241
market as responsible broker-dealers are required to
provide their quotations to FINRA, a not-for-profit
membership organization of broker-dealers. Rule
602(b) and Rule 600(b)(65)(ii) of Regulation NMS.
239 17 CFR 242.604 (previously designated as Rule
11Ac1–4).
240 One commenter asserted that ‘‘exchanges have
government-granted exclusive access to market data
for securities listed in their respective markets.’’
SIFMA I at 12. In fact, a listing exchange does not
have any particular privileges over other exchanges
in attracting quotation and trade data in its listed
stocks. Rather, other exchanges are free to trade
such stocks pursuant to unlisted trading privileges,
and the listing exchange must compete with those
exchanges for order flow. If the listing exchange is
unable to attract order flow, it will not have
quotations or trades to distribute.
241 A straightforward example may help illustrate
this point. Table 1 shows that there are several
exchanges with a very small share of trading
volume. Such an exchange would meet the
statutory definition of an exclusive processor, but
clearly would be unable to exert monopoly pricing
power if it attempted to sell its depth-of-book order
data at an unreasonably high price. Accordingly,
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:01 Dec 08, 2008
Jkt 217001
Commenters cited a decision of the
U.K. competition authorities concerning
proposed acquisitions of the London
Stock Exchange plc (‘‘LSE’’) for the
proposition that an exchange is a
monopolist of its proprietary market
information.242 Their reliance on this
decision is misplaced for two important
reasons. First, unlike the U.S. where the
core data feeds provide an essential
source of information for every
exchange’s most valuable data—its best
quoted prices and last sale
information—the LSE’s proprietary data
is the sole source of information for
trading on the LSE. As a result, market
participants have few, if any, useful
alternatives for LSE proprietary data. In
the U.S., in contrast, the availability of
an exchange’s essential trading
information in the core data feeds, as
well as other valuable alternatives,
discussed above, for assessing market
depth beyond the best quoted prices,
precludes the U.S. exchanges from
exerting monopoly power over the
distribution of their non-core data.
Second, there historically has been very
little effective competition among
markets for order flow in the U.K. The
U.K. Competition Commission, for
example, found that the most important
competitive constraint on the LSE was
not the existence of other trading venues
with significant trading volume in LSElisted stocks, but rather ‘‘primarily, the
threat that [other exchanges, including
foreign exchanges such as the NYSE and
Nasdaq] will expand their services and
compete directly with LSE.’’ 243 In
contrast, the U.S. has a national market
system for trading equities in which
competition is provided not merely by
the threat of other markets attempting to
trade an exchange’s listed products, but
by the on-the-ground existence of
multiple markets with a significant
share of trading in such products. These
competitors also distribute depth-ofbook order products with substantial
liquidity in the same stocks included in
an exchange’s depth-of-book product. In
sum, the competitive forces facing
NYSE Arca in its distribution of
ArcaBook data were entirely
the relevant issue is not whether an exchange falls
within the statutory definition of an exclusive
processor, but whether it is subject to significant
competitive forces in setting the terms for
distribution of its depth-of-book data.
242 NetCoalition IV at 9; SIFMA V at 8.
243 U.K. Competition Commission, A Report on
the Proposed Acquisition of London Stock
Exchange plc by Deutsche Borse AG or Euronext
NV (November 2005), at 57 (emphasis added). The
intensity of competition among markets trading the
same products in Europe could increase
substantially in the wake of the implementation of
MiFID in November 2007.
PO 00000
Frm 00104
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
inapplicable to the LSE in its
distribution of proprietary data in 2005.
In addition, the existence of
significant competitive forces applicable
to NYSE Arca renders inapposite the
citations of commenters to statements in
Exchange Act legislative history and
Commission releases regarding
monopoly data distribution. Such
statements were made in the context of
the central processors of core data for
the Networks, which in fact have
monopoly pricing power for such
mandated data. Central processors of
core data therefore are in a very
different economic and legal position
than NYSE Arca as exclusive processor
for its depth-of-book order data.244
For example, commenters cited a
passage from the legislative history of
the 1975 amendments to the Exchange
Act for the proposition that any
exclusive processor must be considered
a monopoly, but this passage applies
only to the central processors of
consolidated core data that Rule 603(b)
requires to be consolidated:
Despite the diversity of views with respect
to the practical details of a national market
system, all current proposals appear to
assume there will be an exclusive processor
or service bureau to which the exchanges and
the NASD will transmit data and which in
turn will make transactions and quotation
information available to vendors of such
information. Under the composite tape
‘‘plan’’ declared effective by the Commission,
SIAC would serve as this exclusive
244 One commenter cited two papers for the claim
that exchanges have government-conferred
monopolies over the collection and distribution of
trading data. NetCoalition IV at 9–10 (citing Wilkie
Farr & Gallagher, counsel to Bloomberg L.P.,
‘‘Discussion Paper: Competition, Transparency, and
Equal Access to Financial Market Data’’ (September
24, 2002) (submitted by Bloomberg L.P. in
consultation with George A. Hay and Erik R. Sirri);
Erik R. Sirri, ‘‘What glory price? Institutional form
and the changing nature of equity trading’’ (Federal
Reserve Bank of Atlanta 2000 Financial Markets
Conference on e-Finance, October 15–17). Dr. Sirri
currently is Director of the Commission’s Division
of Trading and Markets. The papers were prepared
when he was not a member of the Commission’s
staff. As discussed at length above, the commenter’s
claim that exchanges have a monopoly over the
collection and distribution of trading data confuses
core data, which Commission rules require to be
collected by a central processor pursuant to the
joint-industry Plans, and non-core data, which the
individual exchanges must compete to attract from
market participants. Indeed, the major shifts in
order flow among exchanges and other trading
venues in the years since the papers were written
in 2000 and 2002 amply demonstrate that no
exchange has a monopoly over the collection of
orders displayed in the exchanges’ depth-of-book
data feeds. As noted above (text accompanying note
207), for example, the NYSE’s market share in its
listed stocks has declined from 79.1% in January
2005 to 30.6% in June 2008. For these reasons and
those explained in the text, the two papers are
outdated. Neither the NYSE, nor any other
exchange, currently has a monopoly over the
collection and distribution of depth-of-book order
data in its listed stocks.
E:\FR\FM\09DEN1.SGM
09DEN1
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 237 / Tuesday, December 9, 2008 / Notices
pwalker on PROD1PC71 with NOTICES
processor. The Committee believes that if
such a central facility is to be utilized, the
importance of the manner of its regulation
cannot be overestimated. * * * The
Committee believes that if economics and
sound regulation dictate the establishment of
an exclusive central processor for the
composite tape or any other element of the
national market system, provision must be
made to insure that this central processor is
not under the control or domination of any
particular market center. Any exclusive
processor is, in effect, a public utility, and
thus it must function in a manner which is
absolutely neutral with respect to all market
centers, all market makers, and all private
firms. Although the existence of a
monopolistic processing facility would not
necessarily raise antitrust problems, serious
antitrust questions would be posed if access
to this facility and its services were not
available on reasonable and
nondiscriminatory terms to all in the trade or
its charges were not reasonable.245
These Congressional concerns apply
to a central processor that has no
competitors in the distribution of data
that must be consolidated from all the
markets. They do not apply to the
independent distribution of non-core
data by an individual exchange that is
subject to significant competitive forces.
Commenters on the Draft Order
questioned whether its reliance on
competitive forces is consistent with
Exchange Act legal standards.246 Their
discussion, however, appears to
conflate: (1) The factual issue of
whether competitive forces significantly
constrain the exchanges in setting the
terms for their non-core data; with (2)
the legal issue of whether, if such
competitive forces exist, the
Commission is authorized to consider
those forces in determining whether an
exchange proposal meets the applicable
Exchange Act standards. If an exchange
could, in fact, exert monopoly power
over its pricing of non-core data, it
obviously would be inappropriate for
the Commission to rely on non-existent
competitive forces as a basis for
approving an exchange proposal. If
significant competitive forces do apply
to an exchange, the Commission
believes that considering them in its
review is fully consistent with its
regulatory responsibilities.
For example, the Commission does
not agree with commenters’ argument
that the phrase ‘‘fair and reasonable’’ in
the Exchange Act requires the
Commission always to undertake a costbased review of proposed exchange fees
because it uses such an approach when
applying the fair and reasonable
standard in other circumstances.247
245 Senate
Report at 11–12 (emphasis added).
V at 7–18; SIFMA IX at 8–20.
247 NetCoalition V at 15–18; SIFMA IX at 12–13.
246 NetCoalition
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:01 Dec 08, 2008
Jkt 217001
Applying the abstract standard ‘‘fair and
reasonable’’ to a specific proposal
necessitates the use of factors that are
appropriate to the circumstances. In
assessing the fairness and
reasonableness of a price, courts have
emphasized that the existence of
competitive forces is a particularly
appropriate factor.248
In addition, commenters on the Draft
Order asserted that it improperly relied
on competition to the exclusion of all
others factors.249 In fact, the
Commission considered several factors.
The first step of the market-based
approach to non-core data proposals
examines competitive factors to
determine whether there is a substantial
basis to believe that a proposed fee
meets the applicable Exchange Act
standards. In the second step, the
Commission will evaluate whether there
nevertheless is a substantial
countervailing basis to find that a
proposal is inconsistent with the
Exchange Act, including the unfair
discrimination concerns raised by a
commenter.250
Commenters also cited a passage from
the Commission’s Market Information
Concept Release for the proposition that
an exchange must submit cost data to
justify a proposed fee for the exchange’s
depth-of-book order data.251 The
248 See, e.g., Morgan Stanley Capital Group, Inc.
v. Public Utility Dist. No. 1, 554 U.S. __, 128 S.Ct.
2733, 2738 (2008) (‘‘The statutory requirement that
rates be ‘just and reasonable’ is obviously incapable
of precise judicial definition, and we afford great
deference to the Commission in its rate decisions.
We have repeatedly emphasized that the
Commission is not bound to any one ratemaking
formula.’’) (citations omitted); Elizabethtown Gas
Co. v. FERC, 10 F.3d 866, 870 (D.C. Cir. 1993)
(‘‘[T]he Supreme Court ‘has repeatedly held that the
just and reasonable standard does not compel the
Commission to use any single pricing formula
* * *,’’ and we have indicated that when there is
a competitive market FERC may rely upon marketbased prices in lieu of cost-of-service regulation to
assure a ‘just and reasonable’ result.’’) (citations
omitted).
249 NetCoalition V at 8–9; SIFMA IX at 10–11.
250 SIFMA IX at 11.
251 See section III.A.2 above. As noted in section
III.A.7 above, commenters recommended a variety
of market data regulatory solutions, in addition to
a cost-based justification of fees. One was a
regulatory mandate that exchanges place their
market data operations in separate subsidiaries and
provide their data to third parties on the same terms
they make the data available to the subsidiary.
Given its determination that NYSE Arca was subject
to significant competitive forces in setting the terms
of the Proposal, the Commission does not believe
this regulatory mandate is necessary or appropriate.
It also notes that the recommendation alone would
not address the potential problem of an exchange’s
unreasonably high fees under the per device fee
structure that is used throughout the exchange
industry. For example, the proposed fees for
ArcaBook data would be levied based on the
number of professional and non-professional
subscribers who receive the data on their devices.
Regardless of whether subscribers obtained their
PO 00000
Frm 00105
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
74787
Release stated that ‘‘the total amount of
market information revenues should
remain reasonably related to the cost of
market information.’’ 252 The Market
Information Concept Release, however,
was published in 1999, prior to the start
of decimal trading and to the increased
usefulness of non-core data distributed
outside the Networks. The Market
Information Concept Release in general,
and the cited statement in particular,
solely addressed a central exclusive
processor that has no competitors in
distributing consolidated core data to
the public pursuant to the Plans.253
Moreover, the Commission did not
propose, much less adopt, a ‘‘strictly
cost-of-service (or ‘ratemaking’)
approach to its review of market
information fees in every case,’’ noting
that ‘‘[s]uch an inflexible standard,
although unavoidable in some contexts,
can entail severe practical
difficulties.’’ 254 Rather, the Commission
data from an exchange subsidiary or another
competing vendor, the exchange would receive the
same total amount of fees based on the total number
of subscribers who chose to receive the data. From
the standpoint of maximizing its revenues from per
device fees, the exchange likely would be
indifferent to whether subscribers purchased
through its subsidiary or elsewhere. It therefore
would be willing to make the data available to its
subsidiary for the same per device fees that it made
the data available to third parties. Moreover, to the
extent that an exchange would want to benefit a
subsidiary that it was required to create to act as
a vendor of market data, that requirement need not
cause the exchange to charge lower fees. Instead, it
could create conflicts of interest under which the
exchange would have incentives to favor the
subsidiary over other vendors in ways that might
be difficult to monitor effectively. Under its
proposal, NYSE Arca will make the ArcaBook data
available to vendors on a non-discriminatory basis.
For the same reason that NYSE Arca’s proposed fees
for the ArcaBook data are not unreasonably high—
the competitiveness of the market for that data—
other potential problems cited by commenters as
arising in a non-competitive environment are not an
obstacle to approval of the NYSE Arca proposal
under the relevant Exchange Act provisions and
rules.
252 64 FR at 70627.
253 See, e.g., 64 FR at 70615 (‘‘These [joint-SRO]
plans govern all aspects of the arrangements for
disseminating market information. * * * The plans
also govern two of the most important rights of
ownership of the information—the fees that can be
charged and the distribution of revenues derived
from those fees. As a consequence, no single market
can be said to fully ‘own’ the stream of consolidated
information that is made available to the public.
Although markets and others may assert a
proprietary interest in the information that they
contribute to the stream, the practical effect of
comprehensive federal regulation of market
information is that proprietary interests in this
information are subordinated to the Exchange Act’s
objectives for a national market system.’’)
254 64 FR at 70619. In the Market Information
Concept Release, the Commission discussed the one
context in which it had previously adopted a strict
cost-of-service standard for market data fees—a
denial of access proceeding involving the NASD
and Instinet. See supra, note 47. It emphasized,
however, that the scope of its decision was limited
E:\FR\FM\09DEN1.SGM
Continued
09DEN1
74788
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 237 / Tuesday, December 9, 2008 / Notices
pwalker on PROD1PC71 with NOTICES
concluded that ‘‘Congress, consistent
with its approach to the national market
system in general, granted the
Commission some flexibility in
evaluating the fairness and
reasonableness of market information
fees.’’ 255
Some commenters suggested that
depth-of-book order data has become so
important since the initiation of decimal
trading that broker-dealers now are
effectively required to purchase the
exchanges’ depth-of-book data
products.256 No regulatory requirement,
however, compels broker-dealers to
purchase an exchange’s depth-of-book
order data. As discussed above, only
core data is necessary for broker-dealers
to comply with the consolidated display
requirements of Rule 603(c) of
Regulation NMS.257 In addition, only
core data is necessary to comply with
the trade-through requirements of Rule
611 of Regulation NMS.258
Commenters also asserted that an
exchange’s depth-of-book order data
may be necessary for a broker-dealer to
meet its duty of best execution to its
to the ‘‘particular competitive situation presented in
the proceedings.’’ 64 FR at 70622–70623.
Specifically, the NASD essentially had sought to
charge a retail rate for a wholesale product that
would have severely curtailed the opportunity for
a data vendor like Instinet to compete with the
NASD in the retail market. The practical difficulties
of implementing the strict cost-of-service approach
were amply demonstrated by the long and difficult
history of the attempt to determine the NASD’s cost
of producing the data. See 64 FR at 70623.
255 Id. at 70619. Commenters also pointed to
Commission and staff statements about costs in the
context of the entry of an exchange as a new
participant in one of the Plans. NetCoalition IV at
12–14; SIFMA V at 9–10. Again, competitive forces
are not operative in this context because Rule
603(b) requires an exchange to join the Plans and
disseminate its best quotations and trades through
a central processor in the core data feeds. A costbased analysis is necessary in this context, not
because it is universally required by the Exchange
Act to determine fair and reasonable fees, but
because the absence of competitive forces impels
the use of a regulatory alternative.
256 See section III.A.4 above. Commenters cited a
passage from the Regulation NMS Release for the
proposition that exchanges could exert market
power when distributing non-core data.
NetCoalition III at 6; SIFMA V at 11–12. The
concern mentioned in the Regulation NMS Release,
however, explicitly applied only to the ‘‘best
quotations and trades’’ of an SRO—i.e., an SRO’s
core data—and not to non-core data.
257 Note 183 above and accompanying text. Rule
603(c) requires broker-dealers and vendors, in
certain trading and order-routing contexts, to
provide a consolidated display of the national best
bid and offer and the most recent last sale report.
All of this information is included in the core data
feeds.
258 Note 185 above and accompanying text. When
it adopted RegulationNMS, the Commission
declined to adopt a proposal that would have
extended trade-through protection to depth-of-book
quotations if the market displaying such quotations
voluntarily disseminated them in the consolidated
core quotation stream. Regulation NMS Release, 70
FR at 37529.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:01 Dec 08, 2008
Jkt 217001
customers.259 The Commission believes,
however, that broker-dealers are not
required to obtain depth-of-book order
data, including the NYSE Arca data, to
meet their duty of best execution. For
example, a broker-dealer can satisfy this
duty ‘‘to seek the most favorable terms
reasonably available under the
circumstances for a customer’s
transaction’’ 260 by, among other things,
reviewing executions obtained from
routing orders to a market. Under
established principles of best execution,
a broker-dealer is entitled to consider
the cost and difficulty of trading in a
particular market, including the costs
and difficulty of assessing the liquidity
available in that market, in determining
whether the prices or other benefits
offered by that market are reasonably
available.261 Although the Commission
has urged broker-dealers to ‘‘evaluate
carefully’’ the different options for
execution, we have acknowledged that
cost considerations are legitimate
constraints on what a broker-dealer
must do to obtain best execution.262 In
order to ‘‘evaluate carefully’’ execution
options, a broker-dealer need not
purchase all available market data. The
Commission does not view obtaining
depth-of-book data as a necessary
prerequisite to broker-dealers’ satisfying
the duty of best execution.263
259 See
note 60 above and accompanying text.
Securities Exchange Act Release No.
37619A (Sept. 6, 1996), 61 FR 48290, 48322 (Sept.
12, 1996) (‘‘Order Handling Rules Release’’).
261 See Order Handling Rules Release, 61 FR at
48323 (acknowledging that, consistent with best
execution, broker-dealers may take into account
cost and feasibility of accessing markets and their
price information); Regulation NMS Release, 70 FR
at 37538 n. 341 (noting that the ‘‘cost and difficulty
of executing an order in particular market’’ is a
relevant factor in making a best execution
determination). NYSE Arca and Nasdaq also stated
their view that depth-of-book order products are not
required for best execution purposes. NYSE Arca
Response III at 18; Nasdaq Letter at 5–6.
262 Order Execution Obligations, Proposing
Release, Securities ExchangeAct Release No. 36310
(Sept. 29, 1995), 60 FR 52792 at 52794 (Oct. 10,
1995) (‘‘While not all markets and trading systems
are equally accessible to large and small brokerdealers, and not all order handling technologies are
equally affordable to all broker-dealers, when
efficient and cost-effective systems are readily
accessible, broker-dealers must evaluate carefully
whether they can be used in fulfilling their duty of
best execution.’’).
263 Some broker-dealers may conclude that, as a
business matter to attractcustomers and generate
commissions, they should obtain depth-of-book
order data from one or more exchanges to inform
their order-routing and pricing decisions. As with
any other business decision, if the costs of obtaining
the market data outweigh the benefits, brokerdealers will not buy it. This will put pressure on
the exchange selling the data to lower the price that
it charges. If, however, such firms believed that an
exchange’s depth-of-book order product is
overpriced for certain business purposes, they
could limit their use of the product to other
contexts, such as ‘‘black-box’’ order routing systems
260 See
PO 00000
Frm 00106
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
Commenters on the Draft Order
questioned whether it lowered the
standard of best execution and whether
its reasoning would be accepted in other
legal contexts,264 but the commenters
cited no legal authority to support their
concerns. Moreover, contrary to the
claim that ‘‘ascertaining the total price
of an average retail trade requires depth
of book data,’’ 265 the inferior prices in
depth-of-book data provide a poor basis
to assess the quality of execution of
retail orders. As discussed below, the
availability of substantial undisplayed
liquidity enables such orders to be
executed on average at prices better than
even the best displayed quotes in core
data.266 In sum, the Commission has not
lowered the standard of best execution
by recognizing that there are reasonable
tools other than depth-of-book data to
obtain high-quality executions of
customer orders.
4. Response to Economic Assessments
of the Draft Order
Three commenters submitted
economic assessments (with
supplements) of the Draft Order. The
Ordover/Bamberger Statement agreed
with the Draft Order’s conclusion that
NYSE Arca was subject to significant
competitive forces that constrained its
pricing of the ArcaBook data. It noted
that ‘‘if competition is effective,
regulation is not only not needed, but
can distort the operations of the market
and lead to unforeseen and unintended
consequences that can harm the trading
public.’’ 267
In contrast, the SLCG Study and the
Evans Report disputed the Draft Order’s
conclusion that NYSE Arca was subject
to significant competitive forces. As
discussed below, the Commission has
reviewed their data and analysis and
does not find them persuasive for three
broad reasons:
(1) Although the two assessments
purport to accept that exchanges must
compete to attract order flow, their
theoretical attempts to wall off this
order flow competition from data
and a block trading desk, where the depth-of-book
data feed is most directly used to assess market
depth. The firm would not display the data widely
throughout the firm as a means to minimize the fees
that must be paid for the data. This limited use of
the data would drastically reduce the revenues that
an exchange might have sought to obtain by
charging a high fee and therefore be self-defeating
for the exchange. In sum, exchanges will be subject
to competitive pressures to price their depth-ofbook order data in a way that will promote wider
distribution and greater total revenues.
264 NetCoalition V at 7; SIFMA IX at 19–20.
265 NetCoalition V at 7 (emphasis in original).
266 The execution quality of retail orders is
discussed below at notes 306–308 and
accompanying text.
267 Ordover/Bamberger Statement at 2.
E:\FR\FM\09DEN1.SGM
09DEN1
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 237 / Tuesday, December 9, 2008 / Notices
pwalker on PROD1PC71 with NOTICES
competition are unconvincing—the two
market forces are integrally linked in the
real world of exchange competition;
(2) In rejecting all potential
substitutes for an exchange’s depth-ofbook data, the two economic
assessments focus narrowly on whether
alternatives replicate the exchange’s
specific data and thereby miss the
critically important bigger picture of
whether such data is in fact necessary
for traders effectively to assess the
available liquidity in a stock; and
(3) The two economic assessments fail
to recognize the important ways in
which the Exchange Act regulatory
structure effectively promotes market
data competition, yet suggest regulatory
alternatives that would be costly and
difficult to implement and still would
offer less reason to expect an efficient
outcome than relying primarily on the
current level of competitive forces.
a. Order Flow and Market Data
Competition
Both economic assessments purport to
accept the existence of competition for
order flow among exchanges and other
trading venues.268 They take different
approaches, however, in attempting to
explain why this competition for order
flow does not impose significant
constraints on the exchanges in setting
the terms for their depth-of-book data.
In its analysis of the ‘‘supply-side
conditions’’ of market data, the SLCG
Study says that it will explain ‘‘why
fierce competition among exchanges is
not likely to result in competitively
priced exclusive data when significant
‘network externalities’’ are present in
the market for order flow.’’ 269 Its
analysis is unpersuasive for two primary
reasons. First, if network externalities
are truly operative in the market for
order flow, they should impede
competition for order flow. For
example, the SLCG Study notes that
‘‘[a]t the individual security level, the
order flow externality makes it highly
likely that a dominant liquidityproviding market center will
emerge.’’ 270 The SLCG Study does not
explain, however, how network
externalities could operate in the market
for order flow, impede competition for
market data, but not impede fierce
competition for order flow. If there is
competition for order flow, there
necessarily will be competition for the
supply of market data because order
flow creates the very data to be
supplied, and vice versa. The defect of
the SLCG analysis highlights the
268 SLCG
Study at 2; Evans Report at 2.
Study at 2.
270 SLCG Study at 3.
269 SLCG
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:00 Dec 08, 2008
Jkt 217001
difficulty of separating two aspects of
exchange competition that are integrally
linked.
Second, the SLCG Study attempts to
show that NYSE Euronext and Nasdaq
dominate trading in, respectively,
NYSE-listed stocks and Nasdaq-listed
stocks by offering Herfindahl Index
statistics on market concentration.
Based on these statistics, the SLCG
Study concludes that ‘‘trading is highly
concentrated and that the listing
exchange is the dominant exchange.’’ 271
This conclusion badly misuses the
Herfindahl Index. In particular, a
‘‘concentrated’’ market as measured by
the Herfindahl Index does not mean
there is an absence of competition in the
market. Rather, the U.S. Department of
Justice (‘‘DOJ’’) uses the Index to assess
whether the existing competition in a
market would be substantially lessened
by a proposed merger.272 In this case,
the SLCG Study’s misuse of the
Herfindahl Index is quite apparent,
given that the DOJ specifically found
that the U.S. equity markets were
competitive in November 2005 when it
investigated the merger of NYSE and
Archipelago Holdings and the merger of
Nasdaq and Instinet Group Inc.273 The
DOJ concluded that neither merger
would be ‘‘likely to reduce competition
substantially’’ because the ‘‘planned and
likely entry of several firms * * *
should result in additional viable
alternatives to the two merged firms
sufficient to ensure that the markets
remain competitive.’’ 274
Level of concentration alone does not
reliably indicate the level of
competition in an industry. It is only
one of a series of indicators that may be
used when analyzing competition and is
a more appropriate metric in some
industries than others. In particular,
271 SLCG
Study at 10.
Merger Guidelines § 0.1 (‘‘The Guidelines
aredesigned primarily to articulate the analytical
framework the Agency applies in determining
whether a merger is likely substantially to lessen
competition, not to describe how the Agency will
conduct the litigation of cases that it decides to
bring.’’).
273 U.S. Department of Justice, Press Release No.
05–616, ‘‘Department of Justice Antitrust Division
Statement on the Closings of Its Two Stock
Exchange Investigations’’ (Nov. 16, 2005) (available
at https://www.usdoj.gov/opa/pr/2005/November/
05_at_616.html).
274 See also Comments of the United States
Department of Justice, Review of the Regulatory
Structure Associated with Financial Institutions,
Section III.C. (Jan. 31, 2008) (available at https://
www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/comments/229911.htm)
(‘‘This structure [of the equity markets]—and its
regulatory overlay—permits multiple exchanges
and electronic trading venues to offer the same or
equivalent instruments. There is significant
competition among multiple equity trading venues,
with low execution fees, narrow spreads, and
widespread system innovation—all to the benefit of
consumers.’’); Nasdaq III at 3.
272 DOJ
PO 00000
Frm 00107
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
74789
industry concentration is a more
relevant measure of competitiveness in
markets where barriers to entry enable
large firms to increase equilibrium
prices by restricting the quantity
supplied.275 As the last three years have
shown, new competitors in the U.S.
equity markets have captured significant
trading volume and have imposed
strong competitive pressure on the
primary listing exchanges. Indeed, the
NYSE—the exchange with the highest
market share in its listed stocks in
November 2005—has seen its share of
trading in those stocks drop from 79.1%
to 30.6%.276 This is hardly evidence of
network externalities that ‘‘are such
powerful forces that listing exchanges
are able to survive as natural
monopolies.’’ 277
The U.S. equity markets are
characterized by other key features that
contribute to a competitive outcome
regardless of concentration levels. One
is the ability of firms quickly to expand
their order and trade processing
capacity. As a result, capacity
constraints play at best a minor role in
the way that firms compete for order
flow, and competition is driven
primarily by pricing strategies rather
than quantity choice. A well established
principle of industrial organization
literature is that industries in which
price is the main strategic choice show
more competitive outcomes.278 Another
characteristic of the U.S. equity markets
that promotes competition is low
275 See, e.g., Jean Tirole, The Theory of
IndustrialOrganization 209–221 (1998).
276 See note 207 above and accompanying text.
The SLCG Study and Evans Report asserted that the
Draft Order failed to consider the effect of
competition at the individual stock level, noting, for
example, that Nasdaq’s market share in Nasdaqlisted stocks is higher than for other stocks. SLCG
Study at 11; Evans Report at 7. The Draft Order did,
in fact, consider the market share of NYSE Arca in
various categories of stocks, as well as the NYSE in
NYSE-listed stocks. See 73 FR at 32673. Moreover,
as noted in Table 1 above, no exchange (or even
NYSE and NYSE Arca combined) currently
executes more than 45% of the volume in its listed
stocks. The relatively small variations in market
share across different stocks are consistent with the
Commission’s finding that the exchanges are subject
to significant competitive forces, particularly given
the ready portability of order flow from one
exchange to another (as well evidenced by the
decline in the NYSE’s market share in its listed
stocks). Any attempt by an exchange to capitalize
on its market share in one stock or group of stocks
by acting unreasonably with respect to its
customers is likely to drive that order flow away
and soon end whatever ‘‘dominance’’ the exchange
once had.
277 SLCG Study at 19. See Ordover/Bamberger
Statement at 15 (‘‘HHI analysis can be unreliable
when the shares of firms in the market can change
rapidly (i.e., competition can be vigorous and
intense even in markets in which measured HHI is
high if firms can rapidly gain or lose share.’’).
278 See, e.g., Tirole, note 275 above, at 307–314.
E:\FR\FM\09DEN1.SGM
09DEN1
74790
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 237 / Tuesday, December 9, 2008 / Notices
switching costs.279 Market participants
can easily switch their order flow from
one market to another. Indeed, they can
participate in many markets at the same
time and simultaneously offer and take
liquidity from multiple limit order
books. Finally, promoting competition
is an integral element of the regulatory
structure of the U.S. equity markets. The
Commission has adopted numerous
regulations over the past decade,
including Regulation ATS, the Order
Handling Rules, and Regulation NMS,
that have enabled smaller markets to
compete with larger markets and made
it much more difficult for large
exchanges to retain market share should
they attempt to exert market power. In
sum, the U.S. equity markets have the
hallmarks of an industry in which
concentration is not a very informative
measure of the level of competition.
The calculations in the SLCG Study
also grossly overstate the level of
concentration in the U.S. equity
markets. First, for Nasdaq, the SLCG
Study combines the volume of trades
actually executed by Nasdaq—its
‘‘matched’’ volume—with volume that
is executed by non-exchange trading
venues and merely reported to the joint
FINRA/Nasdaq TRF. The non-exchange
trades do not reflect liquidity in Nasdaq
or in its depth-of-book data. In June
2008, for example, Nasdaq reported
42.7% matched volume in Nasdaq-listed
stocks, while the Nasdaq/FINRA TRF
reported 23.3% volume in Nasdaq-listed
stocks.280 The SLCG Study thereby
erroneously inflated Nasdaq’s market
share by more than 50%.
Second, the SLCG statistics combine
volume for NYSE and NYSE Arca, even
though they operate separate liquidity
pools. As discussed below,281 the
Exchange Act precludes anticompetitive tying of the liquidity pools
of separately registered national
securities exchanges even if they are
under common control. Accordingly,
their separate liquidity pools eliminate
any network externalities between
NYSE and NYSE Arca and undercut
much of the SLCG analysis of market
concentration. The SLCG Study does
not address how network externalities
could apply across separate, untied,
liquidity pools.
Even if the reported market shares of
NYSE and NYSE Arca are combined,
however, it would not change the
Commission’s conclusion that NYSE
Arca faced significant competitive
forces in setting the terms for the
ArcaBook data. The combined market
share of NYSE and NYSE Arca in NYSE-
listed stocks in June 2008 was 44.6%,
down from 53.6% in December 2007,
and comparable to the 42.7% market
share of Nasdaq in Nasdaq-listed stocks
in June 2008.282
The third problem with the SLCG
Study’s calculation of market
concentration is that it fails to examine
the quotes of venues other than NYSE,
NYSE Arca, and Nasdaq when
measuring displayed liquidity—
particularly the quotes of BATS and
Direct Edge, which are the fourth and
fifth largest equity trading centers in the
U.S. Both ECNs display their best quotes
in the core data feeds through either the
International Securities Exchange
(‘‘ISE’’) or National Stock Exchange
(‘‘NSX’’) and offer their depth-of-book
data directly to customers without
charge. BATS also makes depth-of-book
data available to the public without
charge on its Internet Web site.
The displayed liquidity of venues
other than the primary listing exchanges
is quite substantial, resulting in
displayed liquidity concentration that is
much less than reported trading volume
concentration. For example, on July 31,
2008, the best displayed quotations in
the core data feeds for the six stocks
analyzed in the SLCG Report were as
follows: 283
TABLE 2—EXCHANGE QUOTATION COMPARISON SHARE SIZE
[Percent of time at NBBO]
NYSE
C ..........................................................................................
GE ........................................................................................
XOM .....................................................................................
AAPL ....................................................................................
GOOG ..................................................................................
MSFT ...................................................................................
pwalker on PROD1PC71 with NOTICES
The liquidity offered by the ECNs also
is substantial at their depth-of-book
prices outside the best prices that are
included in the core data feeds. For
example, snapshots of BATS depth-ofbook data on July 31, 2008 reflect the
following liquidity available at its best
prices and within four cents away from
its best prices: 284
279 See, e.g., Paul Klemperer, ‘‘Markets
withConsumer Switching Costs,’’ Q.J. Econ. 375–
394 (1987).
280 Source: https://www.nasdaqtrader.com. See
also Nasdaq III at 1–2. SLCG II notes that Nasdaq
itself defines ‘‘total market share’’ to include TRF
trades. SLCG II at 4. Nasdaq’s Form 10–K, however,
specifically distinguishes between ‘‘matched market
share’’ and ‘‘total market share’’ and defines
matched market share to include only transactions
that are executed on Nasdaq’s systems. See Nasdaq,
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:00 Dec 08, 2008
Jkt 217001
2,199 (81%)
2,848 (87%)
883 (49%)
NA
NA
NA
NYSE Arca
Nasdaq
ISE
NSX
5,933
5,728
606
250
212
8,149
8,069
8,594
941
307
194
18,311
4,821 (88%)
4,829 (91%)
470 (63%)
473 (0.4%)
127 (0.1%)
3,848 (8%)
3,948
3,199
576
332
202
10,822
(89%)
(92%)
(77%)
(52%)
(46%)
(95%)
(93%)
(95%)
(75%)
(57%)
(48%)
(97%)
(72%)
(85%)
(22%)
(63%)
(49%)
(95%)
The SLCG Study erroneously
calculated the concentration of
displayed liquidity by extrapolating
Shares at
Shares with- from the reported trading volume of
best prices in four cents BATS and Direct Edge rather than
directly examining their quoted
12,950
39,036
285 It thereby missed an
8,438
37,176 liquidity.
TABLE 3—BATS ORDER BOOK
LIQUIDITY, JULY 31, 2008
C .......................
GE .....................
XOM ..................
AAPL .................
GOOG ...............
MSFT ................
800
400
300
16,200
1,500
2,100
0
60,876
Form 10–K for period ending December 31, 2007
(filed February 25, 2008), at 44–45. Transactions
executed by entities other than Nasdaq and merely
reported to the joint FINRA/Nasdaq TRF are
irrelevant when assessing Nasdaq’s share of
liquidity.
281 Note 309 below and accompanying text.
282 See Table 1, note 210 above and
accompanying text.
283 Source: ArcaVision (available at https://
www.arcavision.com). The data combines bids and
PO 00000
Frm 00108
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
offers to determine size and percentage of time at
the NBBO. For example, if an exchange always
quoted at both the national best bid and the
national best offer for 500 shares, its size would be
1000 shares and its percentage would be 100.
284 Source: BATS (snapshots taken from https://
www.batstrading.com at approximately 11:53 a.m.
on July 31, 2008).
285 SLCG Study at 46. The SLCG Study also
measured all liquidity between the reported high
E:\FR\FM\09DEN1.SGM
09DEN1
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 237 / Tuesday, December 9, 2008 / Notices
pwalker on PROD1PC71 with NOTICES
essential aspect of assessing liquidity in
the current equity markets.
For its part, the Evans Report
recognizes the exceptionally strong
competition for order flow that
characterizes the U.S. equities markets.
Indeed, it describes the ongoing price
war in transaction fees and rebates
among equity trading centers in their
efforts to attract order flow. The Evans
Report concludes, however, that
exchanges are impervious to their
compelling need to attract order flow
when it comes to setting the terms for
their depth-of-book order data. It finds
that the relationship between order flow
competition and depth-of-book data ‘‘is
neither strong nor direct.’’ 286
To support this conclusion, the Evans
Report asserts that transaction fees and
rebates are directly related to order flow
competition, while data fees are not.287
As noted in the Draft Order, however,
the Exchange Act precludes exchanges
from adopting terms for data
distribution that unfairly discriminate
by favoring participants in an
exchange’s market or penalizing
participants in other markets.288
Accordingly, the fact that exchanges do
not directly link their data fees to order
flow providers sheds no light on
whether order flow and market data
competition are related.
The direct connection between order
flow and data competition is based on
‘‘but-for’’ causation—if an exchange
does not compete successfully for order
flow from its customers (in part with
market data), it will not generate
transactions (or transaction fees) and
will have no market data to sell. The
and low price for the trading day (id. at 43), which
at any particular time will include liquidity far
away from the inside prices that is of little value
to traders.
286 Evans Report at 13. One commenter asserted
that exchanges do not have an incentive to keep
market data fees low because they rebate market
data fees to attract order flow. STA Letter at 3; see
also Evans II at 12. Exchange rebates of market data
fees, however, relate to core data fees, not to the
non-core data fees that are the subject of this filing.
Moreover, the exchange rebates of core data fees
apply primarily to trades that are reported to one
of the trade reporting facilities jointly operated by
FINRA and different exchanges. These trades are
executed in the OTC market, not on the exchanges.
The exchanges compete to attract reports of these
trades by rebating core market data revenues to the
entity that actually executed the trade.
Consequently, the market data fee rebates result in
revenues flowing through the exchanges to the OTC
entities that provided the price discovery.
287 Evans Report at 15–16.
288 73 FR at 32762, 32768. See also Ordover/
Bamberger Statement at 17 (‘‘The Commission’s
proscription of ‘discriminatory’ fees for market data
would constrain any attempt by NYSE Arca or
Nasdaq to price discriminate between different
types of customers (i.e., charge higher prices to
customers with relatively inelastic demand for noncore data.’’).
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:00 Dec 08, 2008
Jkt 217001
two types of competition therefore are
integrally connected in the dynamic
process of operating a securities
exchange. This connection pressures
exchanges not to take any action with
respect to market data that might
jeopardize its position in the
competition for order flow. To do
otherwise would jeopardize the
exchange’s own lifeline.
Charging unreasonably high fees for
depth-of-book data would jeopardize an
exchange’s order flow in two respects.
First, wide dissemination of an
exchange’s data is an important tool to
attract order flow.289 The Draft Order
cited the instructive real-world example
when Island ECN stopped displaying its
order book and promptly lost 50% of its
market share.290 The Evans Report
concedes that ‘‘a viable trading venue
must make some of its market data
available,’’ 291 but nevertheless asserts
that this competitive force does not
affect the terms on which an exchange
must make data available to its
customers. An exchange competing to
attract customers is unlikely to be as
sanguine about the effects of an attempt
to charge these customers unreasonably
high fees for its data.292
Second, as noted in the Draft
Order,293 the exchange must market its
data products to many of the same
customers to which it must appeal for
order flow. This integral connection
between order flow and data
competition is strikingly highlighted by
the language of the Evans Report itself:
‘‘[A]n exchange with substantial
liquidity maintains significant leverage
over the consumers of its depth-of-book
data. That dynamic—significant
leverage over market data customers and
little or no leverage over providers and
takers of liquidity—results in prices for
market data that reflect significant
market power and prices for order flow
289 See Thomson Reuters Letter at 3 (‘‘Given the
competitive market for order flow and trade
execution, we agree that ‘an exchange generally will
have strong competitive reasons to price its depthof-book order data so that it will be distributed
widely to those most likely to use it to trade.’ ’’)
(quoting Draft Order).
290 73 FR at 32764.
291 Evans Report at 19. Evans II also states that it
‘‘does not assume that no relationship whatsoever
exists between the pricing of depth-of-book data
and the volume of order flow.’’ Evans II at 11. n.
28. For the reasons discussed in this Order, the
Commission agrees that there is such a relationship.
The Evans analysis appears to disagree primarily
about the strength of that relationship and the
extent to which it significantly constrains the
exchanges in pricing their depth-of-book data.
292 See Ordover/Bamberger Statement at 9 (‘‘large
shifts in trading volume indicate that traders can,
and do, quickly move their orders from one
exchange to another’’).
293 73 FR at 32764.
PO 00000
Frm 00109
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
74791
that reflect competitive conditions.’’ 294
This is a purely theoretical distinction
between customers that does not exist in
the real world in which exchanges must
compete. Exchanges must grapple with
the competitive pressures of marketing
their data services to many of the same
customers to whom they are marketing
their transaction services.
b. Substitutes for Depth-of-Book Data
The two economic assessments
conclude that none of the alternatives
for an exchange’s depth-of-book data
noted in the Draft Order—core data,
depth-of-book data from other trading
centers, pinging for liquidity, and the
threat of independent distribution of
non-core data by broker-dealers—
significantly constrain the pricing of the
exchange’s depth-of-book data. The
Evans Report, for example, focuses on
the unique nature of a particular
exchange’s data and asks whether there
are any substitutes that replicate the
exchange’s ‘‘unique’’ data.295 This focus
is too narrow, however, and fails
capture the bigger picture of what
traders need when they assess liquidity
in a stock and of where an exchange’s
depth-of-book data fits into this
picture.296
The starting point in assessing the
value of liquidity information is to
recognize that price matters a great deal
to traders. The more aggressive the price
of a bid or offer at a particular size, the
more valuable the information is to
traders. Conversely, the less aggressive
the price of a bid or offer, the less
valuable the information is to traders.
An exchange’s depth-of-book data
reflects displayed liquidity at prices
inferior to the quoted NBBO. The value
294 Evans
Report at 17–18.
Report at 6–7. Evans II repeats this
analysis. Evans II at 6. The relevant issue, however,
is not whether the content of one exchange’s data
is a perfect substitute for another exchange’s data.
The issue is whether, given all of the available
sources of information for assessing liquidity and
trading in today’s highly automated and
competitive market structure (which includes both
quoting markets and many dark pools), an
exchange’s depth-of-book data is so critically
important that the exchange is not significantly
constrained by competitive forces in pricing that
data. For the reasons discussed in this Order, the
Commission finds that NYSE Arca was significantly
constrained by competitive forces when it priced its
depth-of-book data at approximately $1.50 per
trading day for market professionals.
296 See Ordover/Bamberger Statement at 7 (‘‘[T]he
amount of available liquidity in depth-of-book data
at prices different from the current [NBBO] is only
a fraction of the liquidity that would be available
at any particular price if the market-clearing price
changed. For this reason, the percentage of trading
in one or more stocks accounted for by any
particular exchange overstates the relative
importance of depth-of-book market data from that
exchange for identifying liquidity that would be
available at prices other than the current NBBO.’’).
295 Evans
E:\FR\FM\09DEN1.SGM
09DEN1
74792
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 237 / Tuesday, December 9, 2008 / Notices
pwalker on PROD1PC71 with NOTICES
of the exchange’s depth-of-book data
therefore does not include: (1)
Undisplayed liquidity at prices better
than the NBBO (available at exchanges,
ECNs, non-exchange liquidity pools,
and OTC market makers), which can be
accessed by pinging orders and can be
tracked (and thereby usefully predicted)
by comparing an exchange’s trade
reports with its best quotes, both of
which are found in core data; (2)
displayed liquidity at the NBBO, which
is provided by the best quotes in core
data; (3) undisplayed liquidity at the
NBBO, which, as with undisplayed
liquidity inside the NBBO, can be
accessed by pinging orders and usefully
predicted with core data.
The reason why these alternative
sources of liquidity information are so
valuable is that traders in today’s
markets almost always prefer to trade at
the current NBBO or better, rather than
accepting the inferior prices reflected in
an exchange’s depth-of-book data.
Because traders naturally prefer to trade
at these better prices, an overwhelming
majority of trades on an exchange are
executed at prices superior to the prices
available in the exchange’s depth-ofbook data. For example, the exchanges’
public reports on order execution
quality under Rule 605 show that the
following percentages of executed share
volume of marketable orders were at
prices equal to or better than the NBBO
in May 2008: Nasdaq—97%, NYSE
Arca—92%, and NYSE—90%.297
Notably, these percentages remain
steady even as order sizes increase from
100 shares to 9999 shares. Stated
another way, more than 90% of the
time, traders do not access the liquidity
displayed in an exchange’s depth-ofbook order data, even for large orders.
Given the inferiority of depth-of-book
prices, the competitive constraints faced
by an exchange in marketing its depthof-book data to professional traders
becomes more understandable. The data
is useful primarily as background
information on liquidity outside the best
prices, but professional traders are able
to use core data and pinging orders to
assess liquidity and trade effectively at
better prices. Moreover, an exchange
that attempted to charge unreasonably
high fees for its depth-of-book data also
would have to consider the actions that
many data users might take to avoid
paying the exchange’s high fees. One
potential alternative would be for firms
297 Source: Rule 605 reports for May 2008 of
NYSE and NYSE Arca (available at https://
www.nyse.com) and Nasdaq (available at https://
www.nasdaqtrader.com). Rule 605 reports cover
orders with sizes up to 9999 shares. The average
trade size for U.S-listed stocks currently is less than
300 shares.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:00 Dec 08, 2008
Jkt 217001
to ‘‘piggyback’’ on the services of
another firm that had purchased the
data, rather than paying the data fee
themselves. For example, buy-side
institutions could use the algorithmic
order routing services of a broker that
had purchased an exchange’s depth-ofbook data, rather than buying the
exchange’s data and routing orders
themselves. The availability of such
alternatives increases the elasticity of
demand for an exchange’s depth-of-book
data.
The information preferences of
securities professionals are strongly
evidenced by the data they currently
choose to purchase. As noted in the
Draft Order, Nasdaq offers its depth-ofbook data product for all U.S.-listed
stocks for $76 per month, or
approximately $3.50 per trading day. Of
the 420,000 professional users who
purchase core data in Nasdaq-listed
stocks, only 19,000 professional users
purchase Nasdaq’s depth-of-book data
product. The Evans Report attempts to
dismiss this fact by claiming that
Nasdaq is a ‘‘monopolist’’ that has ‘‘set
prices above competitive levels so that
only those that value its product highly
will purchase the product.’’ 298 Yet
Nasdaq has priced its depth-of-book
product at a level that is not much more
than the price of a cup of coffee per
trading day. Nasdaq’s pricing decision is
much more consistent with the view
that Nasdaq faces significant
competitive pressures in attempting to
market its depth-of-book data product to
the approximately 400,000 securities
professionals that currently purchase
only core data, than the Evans Report
view that Nasdaq is a monopolist
coercing the 19,000 securities
professionals who are willing to pay
$3.50 for Nasdaq’s ‘‘unique’’ data.299
298 Evans Report at 8 n. 24. The Evans Report also
incorrectly cites revenue figures from Nasdaq’s
2007 Form 10–K for the proposition that Nasdaq
‘‘was able to extract more than 50% of its 2007
market data revenue from its sale of unconsolidated
data.’’ Id. at 17. This analysis overlooks that Nasdaq
separately reports its consolidated data revenues
from non-Nasdaq-listed stocks (known as Network
A and Network B stocks) under a heading called
‘‘Execution and trade reporting revenues.’’ Nasdaq
did not disclose the specific amount of its
consolidated data revenues from Network A and
Network B stocks in 2007, but they were
substantial. For example, the total core data
revenues allocated to SROs in 2004 were $155
million for Network A stocks and $100 million in
Network B stocks (Regulation NMS Release, 70 FR
at 37558). As shown in Table 1 above, Nasdaq
currently has a 23.9% share of trading in Network
A stocks, and its share of trading in Network B
stocks is higher.
299 Nasdaq has priced its depth-of-book data for
NYSE-listed stocks at $6 per month, or
approximately 27 cents per trading day. The SLCG
uses this exceptionally low fee as a basis to assert
that Nasdaq’s $3.50 fee for Nasdaq-listed stocks is
‘‘1,100 higher’’ and evidence of pricing power for
PO 00000
Frm 00110
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
In sum, depth-of-book data is most
accurately characterized as useful, but
not essential, for professional traders.
NYSE Arca has priced the ArcaBook
data for all U.S.-listed stocks at
approximately $1.50 per trading day for
professional users. The Commission
believes that this pricing decision
cannot reasonably be interpreted as that
of a monopolist able to take advantage
of its market power over a small group
of professionals who value the data
highly, but rather that of an exchange
facing significant competitive pressures
in attempting to sell its data to a large
number of professionals.
The Draft Order also noted the
opportunity for new entrants to the
market for non-core data, specifically
noting a comparable initiative in Europe
by a number of major securities firms.300
The Evans Report asserts a myriad of
theoretical obstacles to securities firms
sponsoring a non-core data initiative in
the U.S.301 As noted above, however,
securities firms already have sponsored
new equity trading entrants in the U.S.,
and DOJ—one of the U.S. antitrust
authorities—cited the existence of these
new entrants as support for its finding
that the equity exchange markets are
competitive.302 If securities firms truly
believe that exchanges are attempting to
charge unreasonably high prices for
Nasdaq-listed stocks. SLCG Study at 31. Yet
Nasdaq’s share of trading in NYSE-listed stocks is
a very substantial 23%. Rather than directly
reflecting the value of the data, Nasdaq’s extremely
low fee for NYSE-listed stocks more likely
evidences Nasdaq’s intense efforts to compete for
order flow in NYSE-listed stocks.
300 73 FR at 32765. SIFMA X repeatedly claims
that the proposed NYSE Arca fees are ‘‘excessive,’’
yet also notes that the London Stock Exchange fee
for depth-of-book data is £157.5 per month for nonmembers. SIFMA X at 9. This fee is many times
higher than the proposed NYSE Arca fees that
would total $30 per month for both members and
non-members (based on a pound/dollar conversion
ratio of 1.502 on November 25, 2008, the London
Stock Exchange fee converts to $236.74 per month).
Indeed, the London Stock Exchange fee is much
higher than the fee for any exchange depth-of-book
data product in the U.S., despite the much greater
trading volume and market capitalization of U.S.listed stocks. The lower data fees charged by U.S.
exchanges is yet one more fact evidencing the
significant competitive forces faced by U.S.
exchanges in setting fees for their depth-of-book
data products.
301 Evans Study at 10–12. SIFMA asserted that the
European example is not applicable in the U.S.
because European firms are not required to give
their data to exchanges for free. SIFMA IX at 21 n.
69. As discussed in the Draft Order (73 FR at
32766), however, U.S. firms are not required to
provide the great majority of their orders to any
exchange and, for the balance, have a choice among
exchanges and FINRA. Moreover, if U.S. firms
provided their non-core data without charge to a
new data enterprise, it is not clear why the new
enterprise would operate at a competitive
disadvantage to the exchanges in distributing an
alternative data product.
302 See note 274 above and accompanying text.
E:\FR\FM\09DEN1.SGM
09DEN1
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 237 / Tuesday, December 9, 2008 / Notices
pwalker on PROD1PC71 with NOTICES
their depth-of-book data, participating
in an initiative to offer a competing
source of data is a live option. Indeed,
Thomson Reuters noted in its comment
on the Draft Order that the ability of
broker-dealers to distribute their own
data ‘‘is an undeveloped but important
potential source of market data’’ and
that it is ‘‘prepared to work with the
broker-dealer community to explore
opportunities in the area.’’ 303
Finally, with respect to retail
investors, the SLCG Study asserts that
almost 40% of their orders are for sizes
greater than the displayed size at the
NBBO when presented.304 It then
presumes, without discussion, that
these orders are executed at prices
inferior to the NBBO and that retail
investors need depth-of-book data to
‘‘see the price they are likely to receive
for almost 40% of their orders.’’ 305 This
analysis evidences a profound
misunderstanding of how retail orders
are handled in today’s equity markets.
In particular, the SLCG Study fails to
consider the very substantial availability
of undisplayed liquidity for executing
retail orders at non-exchange venues,
particularly OTC market makers and
liquidity pools sponsored by brokerdealers. This undisplayed liquidity
enables retail investors to receive
executions for most of their orders at
prices equal to or better than the NBBO,
regardless of the displayed size at the
NBBO.306
For example, Schwab’s public
disclosures concerning its order routing
practices and order execution quality
provide an instructive picture of how a
broker-dealer with a substantial number
of retail customers handles their orders
in today’s equity markets.307 Schwab’s
Rule 606 report on order routing for the
quarter ending June 30, 2008 reveals
that 93% of its customer orders in U.S.listed equities were ‘‘non-directed’’—
that is, the customer relied on Schwab
to determine where to route the order.
Schwab routed 94% of these customer
orders to non-exchange trading venues,
rendering it unlikely that either Schwab
or its customers relied on any
303 Thomson Reuters Letter at 3. SIFMA X asserts
that broker-dealers would be unable to create a
competitive depth-of-book data product in the U.S.
because, it claims, they are required to provide their
data to the exchanges. SIFMA X at 9. As discussed
above (text accompanying notes 236–240), the great
majority of a broker-dealer’s orders need not be
provided to any SRO (whether an exchange or
FINRA), and the small subset of a broker-dealer’s
displayable customer orders that must be provided
to an SRO can be provided to FINRA, rather than
an exchange.
304 SLCG Study at 20–21.
305 SLCG Study at 21.
306 73 FR at 32770.
307 Schwab’s disclosures are available at https://
www.schwab.com.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:00 Dec 08, 2008
Jkt 217001
exchange’s depth-of-book data in
making the routing determination for
these orders.308 In addition, Schwab
represents that 57.2% of shares in listed
stocks and 61.3% of shares in Nasdaq
stocks receive price improvement (an
execution price better than the NBBO),
and that the ratio of effective spreads to
quoted spreads for customer orders is
96.5% in listed stocks and 94.7% in
Nasdaq stocks (that is, customers
receive prices on average that are better
than the NBBO). In sum, undisplayed
liquidity at non-exchange trading
centers enabled Schwab customers to
receive executions for their orders at
much superior prices than would be
indicated by any exchange’s depth-ofbook data. The inferior prices reflected
in such data would provide a very poor
basis indeed to assess whether these
retail orders received best execution.
c. Efficacy of Regulatory Alternatives
A third weakness in the SLCG Study
and the Evans Report is their failure to
acknowledge the extent to which the
current Exchange Act regulatory
structure effectively promotes
competition among the U.S. equity
markets. They nevertheless suggest
regulatory approaches that would be
extraordinarily costly and difficult to
implement and that would offer little
chance of achieving a more efficient
outcome than the market-based
approach set forth in the Draft Order.
For example, both the SLCG Study
and the Evans Report assert that the
market shares of NYSE and NYSE Arca
should be combined for purposes of
analyzing market power over depth-ofbook data, even though they are
separately registered as national
securities exchanges and operate
separate liquidity pools with separate
data products and fees. The two
economic assessments note that,
because NYSE and NYSE Arca are
under common control, they will have
an incentive to coordinate their pricing
and not compete with one another.
Exchanges under common control
clearly have incentives to avoid
competing with each other. Each
national securities exchange, however,
is subject to a comprehensive regulatory
structure that is designed to address
anti-competitive practices. This
regulatory structure limits the potential
for related exchanges to act jointly in
ways that would inappropriately inhibit
competition by other exchanges and
trading centers with each related
308 See Nasdaq III at 4 (‘‘Rule 606 data from the
second quarter of 2008 shows that a sample of
major broker-dealers routed just 15% of retail
orders in NASDAQ-listed stocks to an exchange.’’).
PO 00000
Frm 00111
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
74793
exchange. Section 6 of the Exchange Act
requires that the rules of a national
securities exchange be designed to
promote a free and open market.
Moreover, it prohibits a national
securities exchange from adopting rules
that are designed to permit unfair
discrimination among its customers or
that would impose an unnecessary or
inappropriate burden on competition.
All of these requirements are applied at
the level of the individual registered
securities exchange, not at the group
level of exchanges that are under
common control. In particular, a
proposed exchange rule must stand or
fall based, among other things, on the
interests of customers, issuers, brokerdealers, and other persons using the
facilities of that exchange. In sum, an
economic analysis of jointly-controlled
corporate behavior that might apply to
other less regulated industries is
inapplicable to equity exchanges that
are subject to the pro-competitive
Exchange Act regulatory structure.
For example, section 6 and Exchange
Act Rule 603(a) require NYSE Arca to
distribute the ArcaBook data on terms
that are not tied to other products in a
way that is unfairly discriminatory or
anticompetitive. Apparently unaware of
these regulatory requirements, the SLCG
Study claims that the Commission
‘‘does not consider the prospect of the
NYSE exercising monopoly pricing
power through tying arrangements’’ and
notes that ‘‘the NYSE has the clear
incentive to force users of a product in
which an exchange has monopoly
pricing power to also pay for a product
in which the exchange does not have
monopoly pricing power.’’ 309 The SLCG
concerns may be applicable to firms that
operate in unregulated markets, but are
inapplicable to U.S. equity exchanges.
The effect of the U.S. regulatory
structure is apparent when examining
the respective fees for ArcaBook data
and NYSE OpenBook data for NYSElisted stocks. The Evans Report asserts
that these products should not be
considered as alternatives for one
another, but does not address why this
conclusion is valid from the standpoint
of individual users of data when their
use of the two products is not tied in
any way. Customers are free to purchase
both, either, or neither. Each product
must stand or fall on its own merits. The
Evans Report asserts that the revenues
of both products will be retained by the
same corporate entity, yet this point is
irrelevant from the standpoint of
customers who might be looking for
data alternatives. Indeed, if customers
decide that ArcaBook is a better bargain
309 SLCG
E:\FR\FM\09DEN1.SGM
Study at 32.
09DEN1
74794
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 237 / Tuesday, December 9, 2008 / Notices
than OpenBook, a shift between the two
products would lead to a $45 per month
per customer reduction in revenues for
NYSE Euronext. If customers believe
that ArcaBook data is overpriced at $15,
they can purchase OpenBook alone and
NYSE Euronext will have foregone an
opportunity to earn greater revenues by
setting a lower fee for ArcaBook data.
Although the SLCG Study and Evans
Report fail to acknowledge the procompetitive aspects of the Exchange Act
regulatory structure, they nevertheless
suggest alternative regulatory
approaches that would be
extraordinarily intrusive on competitive
forces, as well as quite costly and
difficult to apply in practice. For
example, the Evans Report criticizes the
Draft Order for not addressing whether
an exchange could profitably increase
the price of its depth-of-book data by 5–
10 percent above a ‘‘competitive’’
level,310 but offers no practical guidance
for determining this hypothetical
competitive level. Elsewhere, its author
has noted that ‘‘it seems obvious that
the ability of competition authorities
and courts (or indeed of any economist)
to distinguish between efficient (fair)
and inefficient (unfair) prices in practice
is very low.’’ 311
For its part, the SLCG Study notes
that ‘‘obtaining accurate and precise
data on the marginal costs of producing
a particular good or service (e.g.,
securities market data) is extremely
difficult,’’ but nevertheless asserts that
‘‘there are reasonable alternatives for
assessing levels and trends of marginal
costs.’’ 312 This statement ignores a
whole host of difficulties in calculating
the direct costs and common costs of
market data—an endeavor that the
Commission discussed at length in 1999
and will not repeat here.313 Moreover,
the SLCG Study assumes, without
discussion, that marginal costs would be
the efficiency-enhancing standard to
assess fees for depth-of-book data.
310 Evans
Report at 4.
S. Evans & A. Jorge Padilla, ‘‘Excessive
Prices: Using Economics to Define Administrable
Legal Rules, 1 J. Competition L. & Econ. 97, 118
(March 2005) (‘‘Evans Article’’); see also id. at 99
(‘‘no pricing rule or benchmark can be used to
distinguish effectively (i.e., without error) between
competitive and excessive prices in practice’’).
312 SLCG Study at 26. SIFMA X asserts that there
are numerous choices for reviewing market data
fees other than a strict cost-based analysis, but then
outlines an approach that would require specialized
teams of staff members and administrative hearings
to adjudicate an unspecified ‘‘relationship’’ of a
proposed fee to exchange costs. SIFMA X at 11.
313 Market Data Release, 64 FR at 70627–70630.
See Ordover/Bamberger Statement at 3 n. 4 (‘‘It is
widely accepted that there is no meaningful way to
allocate ‘common costs’ across different joint
products. For this reason, ‘cost-based’ regulation of
the price of market data would require inherently
arbitrary cost allocations.’’).
pwalker on PROD1PC71 with NOTICES
311 David
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:00 Dec 08, 2008
Jkt 217001
Elsewhere, however, the author of the
Evans Report has noted that in
‘‘dynamic industries, where typically
fixed costs are high and incremental
costs are low, the ‘competitive’ price is
not given by marginal costs’’ and that ‘‘it
is impossible to define ‘competitive’
prices using only information costs.’’ 314
The exchange industry is highly
dynamic, and exchanges are dependent
on their ability to deploy cutting edge
technologies. Moreover, the marginal
costs of expanding the capacity of
trading systems are extraordinarily
low—for the most part, a trading center
need only add servers and
communications lines to its existing
hardware and software systems.315
In fulfilling its Exchange Act
regulatory responsibilities, the
Commission is faced with the pragmatic
challenge of determining whether noncore market data fees are fair and
reasonable. It strongly believes that the
current level of competition in the U.S.
equity markets provides a much more
useful basis to make this determination
than a regulatory attempt to measure
market data costs. Although the market
for distributing depth-of-book data may
not meet all of the conditions for
theoretically perfect competition, there
clearly are significant competitive forces
operating in the real world that
constrain the exchanges in setting the
terms for their data. The Commission
therefore has concluded that the marketbased approach outlined in the Draft
Order is the most appropriate means to
meet its regulatory mandate when
reviewing non-core data fees.
C. Review of Terms of the Proposal
As discussed in the preceding section,
NYSE Arca was subject to significant
competitive forces in setting the terms
of the Proposal. The Commission
therefore will approve the Proposal in
the absence of a substantial
countervailing basis to find that its
terms nevertheless fail to meet an
applicable requirement of the Exchange
Act or the rules thereunder.316 An
314 Evans Article at 101; see also id. at 99
(‘‘Unfortunately, it is unclear what the appropriate
competitive benchmark is in most real-life
circumstances and, particularly, in dynamic
industries where investment and innovation play a
paramount role. Moreover, even if an appropriate
benchmark could be defined, it would still remain
unclear how one could, on the basis of the
information typically available to policy makers
and industry analysts, determine with precision
whether prices are above, at, or below the
competitive benchmark in practice.’’).
315 See Nasdaq III at 4 (‘‘The business of operating
a market is typified by low marginal cost for
additional volume and markets operating with
significant excess capacity’’).
316 The Exchange Act requirements are addressed
in the text accompanying notes 171–175 above.
PO 00000
Frm 00112
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
analysis of the Proposal and of the
views of commenters does not provide
such a basis.
First, the proposed fees for ArcaBook
data will apply equally to all
professional subscribers and equally to
all non-professional subscribers (subject
only to the maximum monthly payment
for device fees paid by any broker-dealer
for non-professional subscribers). The
fees therefore do not unreasonably
discriminate among types of
subscribers, such as by favoring
participants in the NYSE Arca market or
penalizing participants in other markets.
Second, the proposed fees for the
ArcaBook data are substantially less
than those charged by other exchanges
for depth-of-book order data. For
example, the NYSE charges a $60 per
month terminal fee for depth-of-book
order data in NYSE-listed stocks.
Similarly, Nasdaq charges a $76 per
month device fee for professional
subscribers to depth-of-book order data
on all NMS stocks. By comparison, the
NYSE Arca fee is 75% less than the
NYSE fee for data in NYSE-listed stocks,
and more than 60% less than the
Nasdaq fee for data in all NMS stocks.
It is reasonable to conclude that
competitive pressures led NYSE Arca to
set a substantially lower fee for its
depth-of-book order data than the fees
charged by other markets. If, in contrast,
NYSE Arca were a monopoly data
provider impervious to competitive
pressures, there would be little reason
for it to set significantly lower fees than
other exchanges.317
Third, NYSE Arca projects that the
total revenues generated by the fee for
ArcaBook data initially will amount to
less than $8 million per year,318 and
that its market data revenue as a
percentage of total revenue is likely to
remain close to the 2005 figure, which
was approximately 17%.319 Viewed in
317 See Table 1, note 210 above and
accompanying text.
318 NYSE Arca Response III at 12 n. 28. The
reasonableness of this projection is supported by
referring to the number of data users that have
subscribed to Nasdaq’s proprietary depth-of-book
product for Nasdaq-listed stocks. Nasdaq reports
19,000 professional users and 12,000 nonprofessional users as of April 30, 2007. Nasdaq
Letter at 6. If the same number of users purchased
ArcaBook data for all stocks, the total revenue for
NYSE Arca would be $8,280,000 per year. As noted
in Table 1, NYSE Arca has a smaller market share
than Nasdaq and therefore may not attract as many
subscribers to its depth-of-book product. On the
other hand, NYSE Arca is charging substantially
less for its data and may attract more users. In the
final analysis, market forces will determine the
actual revenues generated by NYSE Arca’s pricing
decision.
319 NYSE Arca Response III at 12 nn. 28–29. One
commenter noted that the market data revenues of
the NYSE Group, which includes both NYSE and
NYSE Arca, had grown by 33.7% from the third
E:\FR\FM\09DEN1.SGM
09DEN1
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 237 / Tuesday, December 9, 2008 / Notices
pwalker on PROD1PC71 with NOTICES
the context of NYSE Arca’s overall
funding, therefore, the fees for ArcaBook
data are projected to represent a small
portion of NYSE Arca’s market data
revenues and an even smaller portion of
NYSE Arca’s total revenues (using
NYSE Arca’s $8 million estimate, the
fees will amount to less than 12.9% of
NYSE Arca’s 2005 market data revenues
and less than 1.6% of NYSE Arca’s 2005
total revenues). In addition, NYSE Arca
generated approximately $415.4 million
in revenue from equity securities
transaction fees in 2005.320 These
transaction fees are paid by those who
voluntarily choose to submit orders to
NYSE Arca for execution. The fees
therefore are subject to intense
competitive pressure because of NYSE
Arca’s need to attract order flow. In
comparison, the $8 million in projected
annual fees for ArcaBook data do not
appear to be inequitable, unfair, or
unreasonable.
One commenter, although agreeing
that exchange transaction fees are
subject to intense competitive pressure,
asserted that such ‘‘intermarket
competition does not constrain the
exchanges’ pricing of market data, but it
actually creates an incentive for the
exchanges to increase their prices for
data.’’ 321 If, however, NYSE Arca were
truly able to exercise monopoly power
in pricing its non-core data, it likely
would not choose a fee that generates
only a small fraction of the transaction
fees that admittedly are subject to fierce
competitive forces. As discussed above,
NYSE Arca was indeed subject to
significant competitive forces in pricing
the ArcaBook data.
Several commenters expressed
concern that the Proposal would
adversely affect market transparency.322
They noted that NYSE Arca previously
had distributed the ArcaBook data
without charge and asserted that the
new fees could substantially limit the
availability of the data. The Petition, for
example, stated that ‘‘the cumulative
impact of [the Proposal] and other
pending and recently approved market
data proposals threaten to place critical
quarter of 2005 to the third quarter of 2006. See
section III.A.6 above. Although correct, this figure
does not demonstrate any growth in market data
revenues because the 2005 figure only included the
market data revenues of NYSE, while the 2006
figure included the market data revenues of both
the NYSE and NYSE Arca. Using an ‘‘apples-toapples’’ comparison that includes both exchanges
for both time periods, their combined market data
revenues declined slightly from 2005 to 2006. NYSE
Arca Response III at 20.
320 NYSE Group, Inc., Form 10–K for period
ending December 31, 2005 (filed March 31, 2006),
at 19.
321 SIFMA V at 14–15.
322 Financial Services Roundtable Letter at 3;
Schwab Letter at 5.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:00 Dec 08, 2008
Jkt 217001
data, which should be available to the
general public, altogether beyond the
reach of the average retail investor.’’ 323
Assuring the wide availability of
quotation and trade information is a
primary objective of the national market
system.324 With respect to nonprofessional users, and particularly
individual retail investors, the
Commission long has sought to assure
that retail investors have ready access to
the data they need to participate
effectively in the equity markets.
Indeed, the Commission’s 1999 review
of market information was prompted by
a concern that retail investors should
have ready access to affordable market
data through their on-line accounts with
broker-dealers. The Concept Release on
Market Information noted that, in the
course of the 1999 review, the Networks
had reduced by up to 80% the fees for
non-professional subscribers to obtain
core data with the best-priced
quotations and most recent last sale
prices.325 It also emphasized the
importance of such affordable data for
retail investors:
One of the most important functions that
the Commission can perform for retail
investors is to ensure that they have access
to the information they need to protect and
further their own interests. Communications
technology now has progressed to the point
that broad access to real-time market
information should be an affordable option
for most retail investors, as it long has been
for professional investors. This information
could greatly expand the ability of retail
investors to monitor and control their own
securities transactions, including the quality
of execution of their transactions by brokerdealers. The Commission intends to assure
that market information fees applicable to
retail investors do not restrict their access to
market information, in terms of both number
of subscribers and quality of service. In
addition, such fees must not be unreasonably
discriminatory when compared with the fees
charged to professional users of market
information.326
The Commission appreciates the
efforts of the Petitioner and other
commenters in advocating the particular
needs of users of advertiser-supported
Internet Web sites, a great many of
whom are likely to be individual retail
investors. The Commission believes that
the exchanges and other entities that
distribute securities market information
323 Petition
at 3.
11A(a)(1)(C)(iii) of the Exchange Act.
325 Market Information Concept Release, 64 FR at
70614. Since 1999, the Network data fees applicable
to retail investors have either remained the same or
been further reduced. Currently, nonprofessional
investors can obtain unlimited amounts of core data
for no more than $1 per month each for Network
A, B, and C stocks. See SIFMA III, Appendix A.
326 Market Information Concept Release, 64 FR at
70614.
324 Section
PO 00000
Frm 00113
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
74795
will find business-justified ways to
attend to the needs of individual
investors and, as markets evolve,
develop innovative products that meet
the needs of these users and are
affordable in light of the users’
economic circumstances. In this respect,
it recognizes the exchange initiatives to
distribute new types of data products
specifically designed to meet the needs
of Internet users for reference data on
equity prices.327
The Commission does not believe,
however, that the Proposal will
significantly detract from transparency
in the equity markets. Of course, any
increase in fees can lower the marginal
demand for a product. To assess an
effect on transparency, however, the
relevant question is whether the fees for
a particular product deter a significant
number of market participants from
obtaining the market data they need
because the fees are not affordable given
their economic circumstances.328
Market transparency does not require
that the same products be made
available to all users on the same terms
and conditions. Such a one-size-fits-all
approach would ignore the important
differences among data users in terms of
both their needs and their economic
circumstances. Most importantly, such
an approach would fail to address the
particular needs of individual retail
investors.
With respect to professional data
users (i.e., those who earn their living
through the markets), the Commission
believes that competitive forces,
combined with the heightened ability of
professional users to advance their own
interests, will produce an appropriate
level of availability of non-core data.
With respect to non-professional users,
as well, the Commission believes that
the ArcaBook fees will not materially
affect their access to the information
they need to participate effectively in
the equity markets.329 The ArcaBook
data likely is both too narrow and too
broad to meet the needs of most retail
327 See note 19 above (NYSE Real-Time Reference
Prices and Nasdaq Last Sale Data Feeds).
328 See Market Information Concept Release, 64
FR at 70630 (‘‘[T]he relevant Exchange Act question
is whether the fees for particular classes of
subscribers, given their economic circumstances
and their need for and use of real-time information,
are at a sufficiently high level that a significant
number of users are deterred from obtaining the
information or that the quality of their information
services is reduced.’’)
329 See NYSE Arca Response III at 18 (‘‘The
overwhelming majority of retail investors are
unaffected by the inter-market competition over
proprietary depth-of-book products. For them, the
consolidated top-of-book data that the markets
make available under the NMS Plans provides
adequate information on which they can base
trading decisions.’’).
E:\FR\FM\09DEN1.SGM
09DEN1
74796
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 237 / Tuesday, December 9, 2008 / Notices
investors. It likely is too narrow for most
retail investors when they make their
trading and order-routing decisions. The
best prices quoted for a stock in the
ArcaBook data reflect only the NYSE
Arca market. Other markets may be
offering substantially better prices. It is
for this reason that Rule 603(c) of
Regulation NMS requires broker-dealers
and vendors to provide their customers
with a consolidated display of core data
in the context of trading and orderrouting decisions. A consolidated
display includes the national best bid
and offer for a stock, as well as the most
recent last sale for such stock reported
at any market. This consolidated display
thereby gives retail investors a valuable
tool for ascertaining the best prices for
a stock.
Two commenters stated that the
average retail order is 1000 or more
shares and is larger than the size
typically reflected in the consolidated
quotation in core data.330 This issue was
raised, however, when the Commission
was formulating its approach to noncore data in 2005. It noted that the
average execution price for small market
orders (the order type typically used by
retail investors) is very close to, if not
better than, the NBBO.331 In addition, a
study by the Commission’s Office of
Economic Analysis of quoting in 2003
in 3,429 Nasdaq stocks found that the
average displayed depth of quotations at
the NBBO was 1,833 shares—greater
than the size of the average order cited
by commenters.332
Some commenters suggested that the
core data provided by the Networks
disadvantaged retail investors because it
was not distributed as fast as the depthof-book order data obtained directly
from an exchange.333 The central
processors of core data must first obtain
data from each SRO and then
consolidate it into a single data feed for
distribution to the public. While
exchanges are prohibited from
providing their data to direct recipients
any sooner than they provide it to the
Network central processor,334 the
additional step of transmitting data to
the central processor inevitably means
that a direct data feed can be distributed
faster to users than the Network data
330 Schwab
Letter at 1–2; SIFMA IV at 14.
NMS Release, 70 FR at 37567. Most
retail investors receive order executions at prices
equal to or better than the NBBO that is
disseminated in core data. See also Dissent of
Commissioners Cynthia A. Glassman and Paul S.
Atkins to the Adoption of Regulation NMS, 70 FR
37636 (estimating that between 98% and 99% of all
trades did not trade through better-priced bids or
offers).
332 70 FR at 37511 n. 108.
333 Schwab Letter at 4; SIFMA III at 6 n. 11.
334 Regulation NMS Release, 70 FR at 37567.
pwalker on PROD1PC71 with NOTICES
331 Regulation
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:00 Dec 08, 2008
Jkt 217001
feed. The size of this time latency,
however, is extremely small in absolute
terms. For example, a technology
upgrade by the central processor for
Network A and Network B has reduced
the latency of the core data feed to
approximately 3⁄100ths of a second.335
The Commission does not believe that
such a small latency under current
market conditions disadvantages retail
investors in their use of core data, but
rather would be most likely relevant
only to the most sophisticated and
active professional traders with state-ofthe-art systems.
Moreover, outside of trading contexts,
the ArcaBook data will be far broader
than individual investors typically
need. The ArcaBook data encompasses
all quotations for a stock at many prices
that are well away from the current best
prices. For retail investors that are not
trading but simply need a useful
reference price to track the value of their
portfolio and monitor the market, the
enormous volume of data regarding
trading interest outside the best prices is
not needed.336
Some commenters asserted that the
Proposal failed to satisfy the
requirements of Exchange Act Rule 19b–
4 and Form 19b–4.337 Form 19b–4
requires, among other things, that SROs
provide a statement of the purpose of
the proposed rule change and its basis
under the Exchange Act. The statement
must be sufficiently detailed and
specific to support a finding that the
proposed rule change meets the
requirements of the Exchange Act,
including that the proposed rule change
does not unduly burden competition or
efficiency, does not conflict with the
securities laws, and is not inconsistent
with the public interest or the
protection of investors. The NYSE Arca
Proposal met these requirements.
335 NYSE Arca Response III at 21. The upgrade
was completed in April 2007. See Securities
Industry Automation Corporation, Notice to CTA
Recipients, ‘‘Reminder Notice—CQS Unix
Activation—New Source IP Addresses’’ (April 27,
2007) (available at https://www.nysedata.com). This
major upgrade of the CTA data feed runs contrary
to the concern of one commenter on the Draft Order
that exchanges would have little incentive to
maintain the quality of core data. NSX II at 5–6.
336 See NYSE Arca Response II at 2 (‘‘during the
first ten months of 2005 the number of messages
processed by the Exchange greatly increased from
approximately 9,800 MPS [messages per second] to
14,100 MPS’’).
337 See section III.A.3 above. In their comments
on the Draft Order, commenters claimed that it in
effect would amend Rule 19b–4 without following
required agency rulemaking procedures.
NetCoalition V at 7; SIFMA IX at 20. Rule 19b–4,
however, merely sets forth requirements for SROs
to follow in preparing their proposed rule changes.
It does not address the substantive nature of
Commission review of proposed rule changes,
which necessarily will vary widely depending on
the particular issues raised by the SRO proposal.
PO 00000
Frm 00114
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
Among other things, the Proposal noted
that the proposed fees compared
favorably to the fees that other
competing markets charge for similar
products, including those of other
exchanges that previously had been
approved by the Commission.338
One commenter argued that NYSE
Arca should have addressed a number
of specific points that it raised in
opposition to the Proposal, such as
including a statement of costs to
produce the ArcaBook data.339 The
purpose of Form 19b–4, however, is to
elicit information necessary for the
public to provide meaningful comment
on the proposed rule change and for the
Commission to determine whether the
proposed rule change is consistent with
the requirements of the Exchange Act
and the rules thereunder.340 The
Proposal met these objectives. Although
Form 19b–4 requires that a proposed
rule change be accurate, consistent, and
complete, including the information
necessary for the Commission’s review,
the Form does not require SROs to
anticipate and respond in advance to
each of the points that commenters may
raise in opposition to a proposed rule
change. With this Order, the
Commission has determined that the
points raised by the commenter do not
provide a basis to decline to approve the
Proposal.
Finally, commenters raised concerns
regarding the contract terms that will
govern the distribution of ArcaBook
data.341 In particular, one notes that
NYSE Arca has not filed its vendor
distribution agreement with the
Commission for public notice and
comment and Commission approval.342
NYSE Arca has stated, however, that
it plans to use the vendor and subscriber
agreements used by CTA and CQ Plan
Participants (the ‘‘CTA/CQ Vendor and
Subscriber Agreements’’) to govern the
distribution of NYSE Arca Data.
According to the Exchange, the CTA/CQ
Vendor and Subscriber Agreements ‘‘are
drafted as generic one-size-fits-all
agreements and explicitly apply to the
receipt and use of certain market data
that individual exchanges make
available in the same way that they
apply to data made available under the
338 See
Proposal, 71 FR at 33499.
III at 11–12.
340 Section B of the General Instructions for Form
19b–4.
341 See section III.A.7 above.
342 SIFMA I at 7. In this regard, the commenter
states that, procedurally, the Exchange ‘‘is
amending and adding to the CTA vendor agreement
without first submitting its contractual changes
through the CTA’s processes, which are subject to
industry input through the new Advisory
Committee mandated by Regulation NMS.’’ SIFMA
I at 8.
339 SIFMA
E:\FR\FM\09DEN1.SGM
09DEN1
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 237 / Tuesday, December 9, 2008 / Notices
CTA and CQ Plans,’’ and the contracts
need not be amended to cause them to
govern the receipt and use of the
Exchange’s data.343 The Exchange
maintains that because ‘‘the terms and
conditions of the CTA/CQ contracts do
not change in any way with the addition
of the Exchange’s market data * * *
there are no changes for the industry or
Commission to review.’’ 344
The Commission believes that the
Exchange may use the CTA/CQ Vendor
and Subscriber Agreements to govern
the distribution of NYSE Arca Data.345
It notes that the NYSE used the CTA
Vendor Agreement to govern the
distribution of its OpenBook and
Liquidity Quote market data
products.346 Moreover, the Exchange
represents that, following consultations
with vendors and end-users, and in
response to client demand:
[The Exchange] chose to fold itself into an
existing contract and administration system
rather than to burden clients with another set
of market data agreements and another
market data reporting system, both of which
would require clients to commit additional
legal and technical resources to support the
Exchange’s data products.347
In addition, the Exchange has
represented that it is ‘‘not imposing
restrictions on the use or display of its
data beyond those set forth’’ in the
existing CTA/CQ Vendor and Subscriber
Agreements.348 The Commission
343 NYSE
pwalker on PROD1PC71 with NOTICES
344 NYSE
Arca Response I at 3.
Arca Response I at 3 (emphasis in
original).
345 The Commission is not approving the CTA/CQ
Vendor and Subscriber Agreements, which the CTA
and CQ Plan Participants filed with the
Commission as amendments to the CTA and CQ
Plans that were effective on filing with the
Commission pursuant to Rule 608(b)(3)(iii) of
Regulation NMS (previously designated as
Exchange Act Rule 11Aa3–2(c)(3)(iii)). See, e.g.,
Securities Exchange Act Release No. 28407
(September 6, 1990), 55 FR 37276 (September 10,
1990) (File No. 4–2811) (notice of filing and
immediate effectiveness of amendments to the CTA
Plan and the CQ Plan). Rule 608(b)(3)(iii) of
Regulation NMS (previously designated as
Exchange Act Rule 11Aa3–2(c)(3)(iii)) allows a
proposed amendment to a national market system
plan to be put into effect upon filing with the
Commission if the plan sponsors designate the
proposed amendment as involving solely technical
or ministerial matters.
346 Securities Exchange Act Release Nos. 53585
(March 31, 2006), 71 FR 17934 (April 7, 2006)
(order approving File Nos. SR–NYSE–2004–43 and
NYSE–2005–32) (relating to OpenBook); and 51438
(March 28, 2005), 70 FR 17137 (April 4, 2005)
(order approving File No. SR–NYSE–2004–32)
(relating to Liquidity Quote). For the both the
OpenBook and Liquidity Quote products, the NYSE
attached to the CTA Vendor Agreement an Exhibit
C containing additional terms governing the
distribution of those products, which the
Commission specifically approved. NYSE Arca is
not including additional contract terms in the
Proposal.
347 NYSE Arca Response I at 4.
348 NYSE Arca Response I at 3.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:00 Dec 08, 2008
Jkt 217001
therefore does not believe that the
Exchange is amending or adding to such
agreements.
A commenter also stated that the
Exchange has not recognized the rights
of a broker or dealer, established in
Regulation NMS, to distribute its order
information, subject to the condition
that it does so on terms that are fair and
reasonable and not unreasonably
discriminatory.349 In response, the
Exchange states that the CTA/CQ
Vendor and Subscriber Agreements do
not prohibit a broker-dealer member of
an SRO participant in a Plan from
making available to the public
information relating to the orders and
transaction reports that it provides to
the SRO participant.350 Accordingly, the
Commission believes that the Exchange
has acknowledged the rights of a broker
or dealer to distribute its market
information, subject to the requirements
of Rule 603(a) of Regulation NMS.
A commenter also stated that the
Exchange has failed to consider the
administrative burdens that the
proposal would impose, including the
need for broker-dealers to develop
system controls to track ArcaBook
access and usage.351 In response, the
Exchange represents that it has
communicated with its customers to
ensure system readiness and is using ‘‘a
long-standing, well-known, broadlyused administrative system’’ to
minimize the amount of development
effort required to meet the
administrative requirements associated
with the proposal.352 Accordingly, the
Commission believes that NYSE Arca
has reasonably addressed the
administrative requirements associated
with the Proposal.
VII. Conclusion
It is therefore ordered that the earlier
action taken by delegated authority,
Securities Exchange Act Release No.
54597 (October 12, 2006) 71 FR 62029
(October 20, 2006), is set aside and,
pursuant to section 19(b)(2) of the
Exchange Act, the Proposal (SR–
NYSEArca–2006–21) is approved.
By the Commission.
Florence E. Harmon,
Acting Secretary.
[FR Doc. E8–28908 Filed 12–8–08; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 8011–01–P
349 SIFMA
I at 7.
Arca Response I at 4.
351 SIFMA I at 8.
352 NYSE Arca Response I at 4–5.
350 NYSE
PO 00000
Frm 00115
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
74797
SMALL BUSINESS ADMINISTRATION
[Disaster Declaration #11514 and #11557]
Arkansas Disaster Number AR–00026
AGENCY: U.S. Small Business
Administration.
ACTION: Amendment 1.
SUMMARY: This is an amendment of the
Presidential declaration of a major
disaster for Public Assistance Only for
the State of Arkansas (FEMA–1804–DR),
dated 10/22/2008.
Incident: Tropical Storm Ike.
Incident Period: 09/13/2008 through
09/23/2008.
DATES: Effective Date: 11/28/2008.
Physical Loan Application Deadline
Date: 12/22/2008.
Economic Injury (EIDL) Loan
Application Deadline Date: 07/22/2009.
ADDRESSES: Submit completed loan
applications to: U.S. Small Business
Administration, Processing and
Disbursement Center, 14925 Kingsport
Road, Fort Worth, TX 76155.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: A.
Escobar, Office of Disaster Assistance,
U.S. Small Business Administration,
409 3rd Street, SW., Suite 6050,
Washington, DC 20416.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: The notice
of the President’s major disaster
declaration for Private Non-Profit
organizations in the State of Arkansas,
dated 10/22/2008, is hereby amended to
include the following areas as adversely
affected by the disaster.
Primary Counties: Clark, Montgomery,
Nevada, Pike.
All other information in the original
declaration remains unchanged.
(Catalog of Federal Domestic Assistance
Numbers 59002 and 59008)
Herbert L. Mitchell,
Associate Administrator for Disaster
Assistance.
[FR Doc. E8–29115 Filed 12–8–08; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 8025–01–P
SMALL BUSINESS ADMINISTRATION
[Disaster Declaration #11541 and #11542]
California Disaster Number CA–00132
AGENCY: U.S. Small Business
Administration.
ACTION: Amendment 1.
SUMMARY: This is an amendment of the
Presidential declaration of a major
disaster for the State of California
(FEMA–1810–DR), dated 11/18/2008.
Incident: Wildfires.
Incident Period: 11/13/2008 and
continuing through 11/28/2008.
E:\FR\FM\09DEN1.SGM
09DEN1
Agencies
[Federal Register Volume 73, Number 237 (Tuesday, December 9, 2008)]
[Notices]
[Pages 74770-74797]
From the Federal Register Online via the Government Printing Office [www.gpo.gov]
[FR Doc No: E8-28908]
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
SECURITIES AND EXCHANGE COMMISSION
[Release No. 34-59039; File No. SR-NYSEArca-2006-21]
Self-Regulatory Organizations; NYSE Arca, Inc.; Order Setting
Aside Action by Delegated Authority and Approving Proposed Rule Change
Relating to NYSE Arca Data
December 2, 2008.
On May 23, 2006, NYSE Arca, Inc. (``NYSE Arca'' or ``Exchange'')
filed with the Securities and Exchange Commission (``Commission'' or
``SEC''), pursuant to section 19(b)(1) of the Securities Exchange Act
of 1934 (``Exchange Act'') \1\ and Rule 19b-4 thereunder,\2\ a proposed
rule change (``Proposal'') to establish fees for the receipt and use of
certain market data that the Exchange makes available. The Proposal was
published for comment in the Federal Register on June 9, 2006.\3\ On
October 12, 2006, the Commission issued an order, by delegated
authority, approving the Proposal.\4\ On November 6, 2006, NetCoalition
(``Petitioner'') submitted a notice, pursuant to Rule 430 of the
Commission's Rules of Practice, indicating its intention to file a
petition requesting that the Commission review and set aside the
Delegated Order.\5\ On November 8, 2006, the Exchange submitted a
response to the Petitioner's Notice.\6\ On November 15, 2006,
Petitioner submitted its petition requesting that the Commission review
and set aside the Delegated Order.\7\ On December 27, 2006, the
Commission issued an order: (1) Granting Petitioner's request for the
Commission to review the Delegated Order; (2) allowing any party or
other person to file a statement in support of or in opposition to the
action made by delegated authority; and (3) continuing the
effectiveness of the automatic stay provided in Rule 431(e) of the
Commission's Rules of Practice.\8\ The Commission received 25 comments
regarding the Petition.\9\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1\ 15 U.S.C. 78s(b)(1).
\2\ 17 CFR 240.19b-4.
\3\ Securities Exchange Act Release No. 53952 (June 7, 2006), 71
FR 33496 (June 9, 2006).
\4\ Securities Exchange Act Release No. 54597 (October 12, 2006)
71 FR 62029 (October 20, 2006) (``Delegated Order'').
\5\ Letter from Markham C. Erikson, Executive Director and
General Counsel, NetCoalition, to the Honorable Christopher Cox,
Chairman, SEC, dated November 6, 2006 (``Notice'').
\6\ Letter from Mary Yeager, Corporate Secretary, NYSE Arca
Inc., to the Honorable Christopher Cox, Chairman, SEC, dated
November 8, 2006 (``NYSE ARCA Petition Response'').
\7\ Petition for Commission Review submitted by Petitioner,
dated November 14, 2006 (``Petition'').
\8\ Securities Exchange Act Release No. 55011 (December 27,
2006).
\9\ The comments on the Petition, as well as the earlier
comments on the Proposal, are identified and summarized in section
III below. NYSE Arca's responses to the commenters are summarized in
section IV below. Comments on the Draft Order are summarized in
section V below.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
On June 4, 2008, the Commission published notice of a proposed
order (``Draft Order'') approving the NYSE Arca proposed fees to give
the public an additional opportunity to comment.\10\ The Commission
received 16 comments and three economic assessments in response to the
Draft Order.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\10\ Securities Exchange Act Release No. 57917 (June 4, 2008),
73 FR 32751 (June 10, 2008) (``Draft Order'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The Commission has considered the Petition, comments, and economic
assessments submitted in response to the Proposal, Petition, and Draft
Order. For the reasons described below, it is setting aside the earlier
action taken by delegated authority and approving the Proposal
directly.
Table of Contents
I. Introduction
II. Description of Proposal
III. Summary of Comments Received
A. Commenters Opposing the Action by Delegated Authority
1. Need for a Comprehensive Review of Market Data Issues
2. Need for a Cost-Based Justification of Market Data Fees
3. Exchange Act Rule 19b-4 Process
4. Importance of Depth-of-Book Data
5. Lack of Competition in Market Data Pricing
6. Increase in Market Data Revenues
7. Recommended Solutions
B. Commenters Supporting the Action by Delegated Authority
IV. NYSE Arca Responses to Commenters
A. Response to Commenters on Proposal
B. Response to Commenters on Petition
V. Comments on the Draft Order
VI. Discussion
A. Commission Review of Proposals for Distributing Non-Core Data
B. Review of Competitive Forces Applicable to NYSE Arca
1. Competition for Order Flow
2. Availability of Alternatives to ArcaBook Data
[[Page 74771]]
3. Response to Commenters on Competition Issues
4. Response to Economic Assessments of the Draft Order
a. Order Flow and Market Data Competition
b. Substitutes for Depth-of-Book Data
c. Efficacy of Regulatory Alternatives
C. Review of Terms of the Proposal
VII. Conclusion
I. Introduction
The Commission's Rules of Practice set forth procedures for the
review of actions made pursuant to delegated authority. Rule 431(b)(2)
provides that the Commission, in deciding whether to accept or decline
a discretionary review, will consider the factors set forth in Rule
411(b)(2). One of these factors is whether an action pursuant to
delegated authority embodies a decision of law or policy that is
important and that the Commission should review.
The Petitioner and commenters raised a number of important issues
that the Commission believes it should address directly at this time.
In particular, section VI below addresses issues related to the nature
of the Commission's review of proposed rule changes for the
distribution of ``non-core'' market data, which includes the NYSE Arca
data that is the subject of the Proposal. Individual exchanges and
other market participants distribute non-core data independently. Non-
core data should be contrasted with ``core'' data--the best-priced
quotations and last sale information of all markets in U.S.-listed
equities that Commission rules require to be consolidated and
distributed to the public by a single central processor.\11\ Pursuant
to the authority granted by Congress under section 11A of the Exchange
Act, the Commission requires the self-regulatory organizations
(``SROs'') to participate in joint-industry plans for disseminating
core data, and requires broker-dealers and vendors to display core data
to investors to help inform their trading and order-routing decisions.
In contrast, no Commission rule requires exchanges or market
participants either to distribute non-core data to the public or to
display non-core data to investors.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\11\ See section VI.A below for a fuller discussion of the
arrangements for distributing core and non-core data.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Price transparency is critically important to the efficient
functioning of the equity markets. In 2006, the core data feeds
reported prices for more than $39.4 trillion in transactions in U.S.-
listed equities.\12\ In 2006, U.S. broker-dealers earned $21.7 billion
in commissions from trading in U.S.-listed equities--an amount that
does not include any revenues from proprietary trading by U.S. broker-
dealers or other market participants.\13\ Approximately 420,000
securities industry professionals subscribe to the core data products
of the joint-industry plans, while only about 5% of these professionals
have chosen to subscribe to the non-core data products of
exchanges.\14\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\12\ Source: ArcaVision (available at https://
www.arcavision.com).
\13\ Frank A. Fernandez, Securities Industry and Financial
Markets Association Research Report, ``Securities Industry Financial
Results: 2006'' (May 2, 2006) (``SIFMA Research Report''), at 7-9,
21.
\14\ See note 233 below and accompanying text.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
In June 2008, NYSE Arca executed a 16.5% share of trading in U.S.-
listed equities.\15\ The reasonably projected revenues from the
proposed fees for NYSE Arca's non-core data are $8 million per
year.\16\ Commenters opposing the Proposal claimed that NYSE Arca
exercised monopoly power to set excessive fees for its non-core data
and recommended that the Commission adopt a ``cost-of-service''
ratemaking approach when reviewing exchange fees for non-core data--an
approach comparable to the one traditionally applied to utility
monopolies.\17\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\15\ See note 205 below and accompanying text.
\16\ See note 318 below and accompanying text.
\17\ The commenters' views are summarized in section III.A.2
below.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
In 2005, however, the Commission stated its intention to apply a
market-based approach that relies primarily on competitive forces to
determine the terms on which non-core data is made available to
investors.\18\ This approach follows the clear intent of Congress in
adopting section 11A of the Exchange Act that, whenever possible,
competitive forces should dictate the services and practices that
constitute the U.S. national market system for trading equity
securities. Section VI discusses this market-based approach and applies
it in the specific context of the Proposal by NYSE Arca. The Commission
is approving the Proposal primarily because NYSE Arca was subject to
significant competitive forces in setting the terms of the Proposal.
The Commission believes that reliance on competitive forces, whenever
possible, is the most effective means to assess whether proposed fees
for non-core data meet the applicable statutory requirements.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\18\ Securities Exchange Act Release No. 51808 (June 9, 2005),
70 FR 37496, 37566-37568 (June 29, 2005) (``Regulation NMS
Release'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The Petitioner and commenters discussed and recommended solutions
for a wide range of market data issues that were beyond the scope of
the Proposal. The Petitioner particularly called attention to the data
needs of users of advertiser-supported Internet Web sites, many of whom
are individual retail investors. In this regard, the Commission
recognizes that exchanges have responded by developing innovative new
data products specifically designed to meet the reference data needs
and economic circumstances of these Internet users.\19\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\19\ See Securities Exchange Act Release No. 57966 (June 16,
2008), 73 FR 35182 (June 20, 2008) (File No. SR-NYSE-2007-04) (NYSE
Real-Time Reference Prices); Securities Exchange Act Release No.
57965 (June 16, 2008), 73 FR 35178 (June 20, 2008) (SR-NASDAQ-2006-
060) (Nasdaq Last Sale Data Feeds).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
As noted in section III.A.1 below, some commenters also suggested
that, pending a comprehensive resolution of all market data issues
(including those related to core data), the Commission should impose a
moratorium on all proposed rule changes related to market data. The
Commission recognizes the importance of many of the issues raised by
commenters relating to core data that are beyond the scope of the
Proposal. It is continuing to consider these issues, and others, as
part of its ongoing review of SRO structure, governance, and
transparency.\20\ The Commission does not, however, believe that
imposing a moratorium on the review of proposed rule changes related to
market data products and fees would be appropriate or consistent with
the Exchange Act. A primary Exchange Act objective for the national
market system is to promote fair competition.\21\ Failing to act on the
proposed rule changes of particular exchanges would be inconsistent
with this Exchange Act objective, as well as with the requirements
pertaining to SRO rule filings more generally. Accordingly, the
Commission will continue to act on proposed rule changes for the
distribution of market data in accordance with the applicable Exchange
Act requirements.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\20\ See Securities Exchange Act Release No. 50699 (November 18,
2004), 69 FR 71126 (December 8, 2004) (proposed rules addressing SRO
governance and transparency); Securities Exchange Act Release No.
50700 (November 18, 2004), 69 FR 71256 (December 8, 2004) (``Concept
Release Concerning Self-Regulation'').
\21\ Section 11A(a)(1)(C)(ii) of the Exchange Act, 15 U.S.C.
78k-1(a)(1)(C)(ii).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
II. Description of Proposal
Through NYSE Arca, LLC, the equities trading facility of NYSE Arca
Equities, Inc., the Exchange makes available on a real-time basis
ArcaBook\SM\, a compilation of all limit orders resident in the NYSE
Arca limit order book. In addition, the Exchange makes available real-
time information relating to transactions and limit orders in debt
securities that are traded
[[Page 74772]]
through the Exchange's facilities. The Exchange makes ArcaBook and the
bond transaction and limit order information (collectively, ``NYSE Arca
Data'') available to market data vendors, broker-dealers, private
network providers, and other entities by means of data feeds.
Currently, the Exchange does not charge fees for the receipt and use of
NYSE Arca Data.
The Exchange's proposal would establish fees for the receipt and
use of NYSE Arca Data. Specifically, the Exchange proposes to establish
a $750 per month access fee for access to the Exchange's data feeds
that carry the NYSE Arca Data. In addition, the Exchange proposes to
establish professional and non-professional device fees for the NYSE
Arca Data.\22\ For professional subscribers, the Exchange proposes to
establish a monthly fee of $15 per device for the receipt of ArcaBook
data relating to exchange-traded funds (``ETFs'') and those equity
securities for which reporting is governed by the CTA Plan (``CTA Plan
and ETF Securities'') and a monthly fee of $15 per device for the
receipt of ArcaBook data relating to those equity securities, excluding
ETFs, for which reporting is governed by the Nasdaq UTP Plan (``Nasdaq
UTP Plan Securities'').\23\ For non-professional subscribers, the
Exchange proposes to establish a monthly fee of $5 per device for the
receipt of ArcaBook data relating to CTA Plan and ETF Securities and a
monthly fee of $5 per device for the receipt of ArcaBook data relating
to Nasdaq UTP Plan Securities.\24\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\22\ In differentiating between professional and non-
professional subscribers, the Exchange proposes to apply the same
criteria used by the Consolidated Tape Association Plan (``CTA
Plan'') and the Consolidated Quotation Plan (``CQ Plan'') for
qualification as a non-professional subscriber. The two plans, which
have been approved by the Commission, are available at https://
www.nysedata.com.
\23\ The ``Nasdaq UTP Plan'' is the Joint Self-Regulatory
Organization Plan Governing the Collection, Consolidation and
Dissemination of Quotation and Transaction Information for Nasdaq-
Listed Securities Traded on Exchanges on an Unlisted Trading
Privileges Basis. The plan, which has been approved by the
Commission, is available at https://www.utpdata.com.
\24\ There will be no monthly device fees for limit order and
last sale price information relating to debt securities traded
through the Exchange's facilities.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The Exchange also proposes a maximum monthly payment for device
fees paid by any broker-dealer for non-professional subscribers that
maintain brokerage accounts with the broker-dealer.\25\ For 2006, the
Exchange proposed a $20,000 maximum monthly payment. For the months
falling in a subsequent calendar year, the maximum monthly payment will
increase (but not decrease) by the percentage increase (if any) in the
annual composite share volume \26\ for the calendar year preceding that
subsequent calendar year, subject to a maximum annual increase of five
percent.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\25\ Professional subscribers may be included in the calculation
of the monthly maximum amount so long as: (1) Nonprofessional
subscribers comprise no less than 90% of the pool of subscribers
that are included in the calculation; (2) each professional
subscriber that is included in the calculation is not affiliated
with the broker-dealer or any of its affiliates (either as an
officer, partner or employee or otherwise); and (3) each such
professional subscriber maintains a brokerage account directly with
the broker-dealer (that is, with the broker-dealer rather than with
a correspondent firm of the broker-dealer).
\26\ ``Composite share volume'' for a calendar year refers to
the aggregate number of shares in all securities that trade over
NYSE Arca facilities for that calendar year.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Lastly, the Exchange proposes to waive the device fees for ArcaBook
data during the duration of the billable month in which a subscriber
first gains access to the data.
III. Summary of Comments Received
The Commission received four comments from three commenters
regarding the Proposal after it was published for comment.\27\ NYSE
Arca responded to the comments.\28\ After granting the Petition, the
Commission received 25 comments from 17 commenters regarding the
approval of the Proposal by delegated authority.\29\ Nine commenters
urged the Commission to set aside the action by delegated
authority,\30\ and five commenters supported the action by delegated
authority.\31\ One commenter expressed no views regarding the specifics
of the Proposal, but urged the Commission to address market data fees
as part of a more comprehensive modernization of SROs in light of
recent market structure developments.\32\ NYSE Arca responded to the
comments submitted after the Commission granted the Petition.\33\ Three
commenters submitted additional comments
[[Page 74773]]
addressing NYSE Arca's response and arguments raised by other
commenters, or provided additional information.\34\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\27\ Web comment from Steven C. Spencer, dated June 18, 2006
(``Spencer Letter''); letter from Markham C. Erickson, Executive
Director and General Counsel, NetCoalition, to Christopher Cox,
Chairman, Commission, dated August 9, 2006 (``NetCoalition I''); and
letters from Gregory Babyak, Chairman, Market Data Subcommittee of
the Securities Industry Association (``SIA'') Technology and
Regulation Committee, and Christopher Gilkerson, Chairman, SIA
Technology and Regulation Committee, to Nancy Morris, Secretary,
Commission, dated June 30, 2006 (``SIFMA I'') and August 18, 2006
(``SIFMA II''). The SIA has merged into the Securities Industry and
Financial Markets Association (``SIFMA'').
\28\ Letters from Janet Angstadt, Acting General Counsel, NYSE
Arca, to Nancy J. Morris, Secretary, Commission, dated July 25, 2006
(``NYSE Arca Response I''), and August 25, 2006 (``NYSE Arca
Response II'').
\29\ Letters from Christopher Gilkerson and Gregory Babyak, Co-
Chairs, Market Data Subcommittee of SIFMA Technology and Regulation
Committee, dated February 14, 2008 (``SIFMA VIII''); Ira D.
Hammerman, Senior Managing Director and General Counsel, SIFMA,
dated February 7, 2007 (``SIFMA VII''); Markham C. Erickson,
Executive Director and General Counsel, NetCoalition, dated January
11, 2008 (``NetCoalition V''); The Honorable Paul E. Kanjorski,
Chairman, Subcommittee on Capital Markets, Insurance, and Government
Sponsored Enterprises, dated December 12, 2007 (``Kanjorski
Letter''); Melissa MacGregor, Vice President and Assistant General
Counsel, SIFMA, dated November 7, 2007 (``SIFMA VI''); The Honorable
Richard H. Baker, Member of Congress, dated October 1, 2007 (``Baker
Letter''); Markham C. Erickson, Executive Director and General
Counsel, NetCoalition, dated September 14, 2007 (``NetCoalition
IV''); Ira D. Hammerman, Senior Managing Director and General
Counsel, SIFMA, dated August 1, 2007 (``SIFMA V''); Jeffrey Davis,
Vice President and Deputy General Counsel, The Nasdaq Stock Market
(``Nasdaq''), dated May 18, 2007 (``Nasdaq Letter''); David T.
Hirschmann, Senior Vice President, Chamber of Commerce of the United
States of America, dated May 3, 2007 (``Chamber of Commerce
Letter''); Markham C. Erickson, Executive Director and General
Counsel, NetCoalition, dated March 6, 2007 (``NetCoalition III'');
Ira D. Hammerman, Senior Managing Director and General Counsel,
SIFMA, dated March 5, 2007 (``SIFMA IV''); Joseph Rizzello, Chief
Executive Officer, National Stock Exchange (``NSX''), dated February
27, 2007 (``NSX Letter''); Keith F. Higgins, Chair, Committee on
Federal Regulation of Securities, American Bar Association
(``ABA''), dated February 12, 2007 (``ABA Letter''); James A.
Forese, Managing Director and Head of Global Equities, Citigroup
Global Markets Inc. (``Citigroup''), dated February 5, 2007
(``Citigroup Letter''); Meyer S. Frucher, Chairman and Chief
Executive Officer, PHLX, dated January 31, 2007 (``PHLX Letter'');
Amex, Boston Stock Exchange, Chicago Board Options Exchange, Chicago
Stock Exchange, ISE, The Nasdaq Stock Market, NYSE, NYSE Arca, and
Philadelphia Stock Exchange (``PHLX'') (collectively, the ``Exchange
Market Data Coalition''), dated January 26, 2007 (``Exchange Market
Data Coalition Letter''); Oscar N. Onyema, Senior Vice President and
Chief Administrative Officer, American Stock Exchange LLC
(``Amex''), dated January 18, 2007 (``Amex Letter''); Sanjiv Gupta,
Bloomberg, dated January 17, 2007 (``Bloomberg Letter''); Richard M.
Whiting, Executive Director and General Counsel, Financial Services
Roundtable, dated January 17, 2007 (``Financial Services Roundtable
Letter''); Markham C. Erickson, Executive Director and General
Counsel, NetCoalition, dated January 17, 2007 (``NetCoalition II'');
Michael J. Simon, Secretary, International Securities Exchange, LLC
(``ISE''), dated January 17, 2007 (``ISE Letter''); Jeffrey T.
Brown, Senior Vice President, Office of Legislative and Regulatory
Affairs, Charles Schwab & Co., Inc. (``Schwab''), dated January 17,
2007 (``Schwab Letter''); and Ira Hammerman, Senior Managing
Director and General Counsel, SIFMA, dated January 17, 2007 (``SIFMA
III''); and letter from David Keith, Vice President, Web Products
and Solutions, The Globe and Mail, to the Honorable Christopher Cox,
Chairman, Commission, dated January 17, 2007 (``Globe and Mail
Letter'').
\30\ SIFMA III and IV, and Bloomberg, Chamber of Commerce,
Citigroup, Financial Services Roundtable, Globe and Mail,
NetCoalition, NSX, and Schwab Letters.
\31\ Amex, Exchange Market Data Coalition, ISE, Nasdaq, and PHLX
Letters.
\32\ ABA Letter at 1.
\33\ Letter from Mary Yeager, Corporate Secretary, NYSE Arca, to
the Honorable Christopher Cox, Chairman, Commission, dated February
6, 2007 (``NYSE Arca Response III'').
\34\ Nasdaq Letter; SIFMA IV, V, and VI; NetCoalition III and
IV.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The comments submitted in connection with the Proposal and the
Petition are summarized in this section. NYSE Arca's responses are
summarized in section IV below.
A. Commenters Opposing the Action by Delegated Authority
1. Need for a Comprehensive Review of Market Data Issues
Several commenters seeking a reversal of the staff's approval of
the Proposal by delegated authority believed that recent regulatory and
market structure developments warrant a broader review of market data
fees and of the Commission's procedures for reviewing and evaluating
market data proposals.\35\ According to these commenters, these
developments include the transformation of most U.S. securities
exchanges into for-profit entities; the increasing importance of
single-market depth-of-book information following decimalization and
the adoption of Regulation NMS; and the absence of competitive forces
that could limit the fees that an exchange may charge for its depth-of-
book data. Some commenters believed that the Commission should consider
not only market data fees, but also the contract terms governing the
use of an exchange's market data, which may impose additional costs and
include restrictions on the use of the data.\36\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\35\ Citigroup Letter at 2; SIFMA III at 10, 26; SIFMA IV at 15.
See also ABA Letter at 1; Bloomberg Letter at 7-8; NetCoalition I at
2; NetCoalition III at 13. Among other things, the Bloomberg and
Citigroup Letters support the recommendations in SIFMA III.
Bloomberg Letter at 8 n. 19; Citigroup Letter at 1.
\36\ Citigroup Letter at 2; SIFMA III at 23.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
In light of the significance and complexity of the issues raised,
several commenters asked the Commission not only to reverse the staff's
action, but also to impose a moratorium on the approval or processing
of market data proposals while the Commission conducts a broader review
of the issues associated with market data, including ``the underlying
issues of market structure, market power, transparency, and ease of
dissemination and analysis of market data.'' \37\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\37\ Citigroup Letter at 2. See also ABA Letter at 3; Financial
Services Roundtable Letter at 1; NetCoalition III at 13; Schwab
Letter at 1; SIFMA III at 26; SIFMA IV at 15.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
2. Need for a Cost-Based Justification of Market Data Fees
Several commenters argued that the staff erred in approving the
Proposal because NYSE Arca did not provide a cost-based justification
for the Proposal's market data fees or other evidence to demonstrate
that its proposed fees meet the applicable Exchange Act standards.\38\
They asserted that the Exchange Act requires that an exchange's market
data fees be ``fair and reasonable,'' ``not unreasonably
discriminatory,'' and ``an equitable allocation of costs,'' \39\ and
that the Commission apply a cost-based standard in evaluating market
data fees.\40\ One commenter argued that market data fees ``must be
reasonably related to market data costs'' and that the Commission
should require exchanges to identify and substantiate their market data
costs in their market data fee proposals.\41\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\38\ Bloomberg Letter at 3; Petition at 5; SIFMA I at 6; SIFMA
III at 20.
\39\ Schwab Letter at 4; SIFMA III at 19; SIFMA IV at 7.
\40\ Bloomberg Letter at 2; NetCoalition II at 3; NetCoalition
III at 11; Schwab Letter at 3; SIFMA I at 6; SIFMA III at 16; SIFMA
IV at 10.
\41\ SIFMA III at 1, 20.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Several commenters argued that the Commission itself has recognized
the need for a cost-based justification of market data fees.\42\ They
believed that the Commission's position in its 1999 market information
concept release \43\ ``underscores the fundamental role that a rigorous
cost-based analysis must play in reviewing market data fee filings.''
\44\ In particular, these commenters cited the following statement from
the release:
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\42\ Bloomberg Letter at 2; NetCoalition II at 3; NetCoalition
III at 11; Schwab Letter at 3; SIFMA III at 20; SIFMA IV at 10.
\43\ Securities Exchange Act Release No. 42208 (December 9,
1999), 64 FR 70613 (December 17, 1999) (``Market Information Concept
Release'').
\44\ NetCoalition II at 3. See also Bloomberg Letter at 2; SIFMA
I at 6.
[T]he fees charged by a monopolistic provider of a service (such
as the exclusive processors of market information) need to be tied
to some type of cost-based standard in order to preclude excessive
profits if fees are too high or underfunding or subsidization if
fees are too low. The Commission therefore believes that the total
amount of market information revenues should remain reasonably
related to the cost of market information.\45\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\45\ 64 FR at 70627 (cited in Bloomberg Letter at 2;
NetCoalition II at 3; NetCoalition III at 11 n. 47; SIFMA III at 1).
One commenter maintained that the cost-based analysis requirement is
based on Congressional concerns regarding the dangers of exclusive
processors, in the context of either consolidated or single-market
data. NetCoalition II at 3.
Similarly, a commenter stated that the Commission acknowledged in
its Concept Release Concerning Self-Regulation that the amount of
market data revenues should be reasonably related to the cost of market
information.\46\ Another commenter, citing proceedings involving
Instinet's challenge to proposed NASD market data fees,\47\ argued that
the Commission in that case ``emphatically embraced the cost-based
approach to setting market data fees * * *,'' and insisted on a strict
cost-based justification for the market data fees at issue.\48\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\46\ NetCoalition III at 11 n. 47.
\47\ Securities Exchange Act Release No. 20874 (April 17, 1984),
49 FR 17640 (April 24, 1984), aff'd sub nom. NASD, Inc. v. SEC, 802
F.2d 1415 (D.C. Cir. 1986).
\48\ SIFMA IV at 10.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The commenters believed, further, that the costs attributable to
market data should be limited to the cost of collecting, consolidating,
and distributing the data,\49\ and that market data fees should not be
used to fund regulatory activities or to cross-subsidize an exchange's
competitive operations.\50\ One commenter maintained that, in the
absence of cost data, the Commission cannot determine whether NYSE Arca
uses market data revenues to subsidize competitive activities.\51\ In
particular, the commenter believed that the Commission must scrutinize
the cost justification for NYSE Arca's fees to ``be sure that NYSE Arca
is not using its market power in the upstream data market as the
exclusive processor for this data * * * to price squeeze its
competitors in the downstream transaction market and to cross-subsidize
its reduction in transaction fees.'' \52\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\49\ Citigroup Letter at 1; SIFMA III at 21. One commenter
believed that the Commission ``should create standards that allow
producers of market data to recover their costs and make a
reasonable profit (e.g., a 10% return), but not an excessive
profit.'' Schwab Letter at 6.
\50\ SIFMA III at 8; SIFMA IV at 10. The commenter believed that
other costs, including member regulation and market surveillance,
should be funded by listing, trading, and regulatory fees, rather
than market data fees. See SIFMA III at 21. Another commenter
maintained that funding regulatory activities through an explicit
regulatory fee, rather than through market data revenues, ``would be
more logical and transparent * * *.'' NSX Letter at 2. See also
Schwab Letter at 5.
\51\ SIFMA IV at 10.
\52\ SIFMA IV at 10.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
One commenter argued that NYSE Arca's proposed fees are not an
``equitable allocation'' of costs among its users and are unreasonably
discriminatory because the fees are based on the number of people who
view the data. Thus, a broker-dealer with many customers seeking to
view
[[Page 74774]]
market data pays considerably more for market data than an institution
or algorithmic trader that pays only for the data link to its computer
systems.\53\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\53\ Schwab Letter at 4. The commenter argued that this fee
structure ``is a subsidization program whereby exchanges rebate
revenue to their favored traders based on market data fees imposed
on retail investors.'' Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
3. Exchange Act Rule 19b-4 Process
One commenter argued that the Proposal fails to satisfy the
requirements of Exchange Act Rule 19b-4 and Form 19b-4, because, among
other things, the Proposal does not: (1) Explain why NYSE Arca must
charge for data that it previously provided free of charge; (2) address
the change in circumstances caused by the NYSE's conversion from a
member-owned, not-for-profit entity to a shareholder-owned, for-profit
entity; (3) address the effect of the fee on retail investors, whom the
commenter believes will be denied access to NYSE Arca's data as a
result of the fees; (4) explain how making available a faster single-
market data feed at a high price, while most investors must rely on
slower consolidated market data products, is consistent with the
mandates under the Exchange Act for equal access to and transparency in
market data; and (5) include the contract terms governing access to and
use of NYSE Arca's data or address the administrative costs and burdens
that the contract terms impose.\54\ Another commenter, citing the
Petition, asserted that the Proposal fails to satisfy the requirements
of Form 19b-4 because it provides no disclosure regarding the burdens
on competition that could result from its proposed fees or a
justification for the proposed fees.\55\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\54\ SIFMA III at 11-12.
\55\ Bloomberg Letter at 3. See also Petition at 6-7.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Commenters also raised more general concerns regarding the Exchange
Act Rule 19b-4 rule filing process as it applies to proposed rule
changes relating to market data. In light of the significant policy
issues that market data proposals raise, commenters questioned whether
such proposals should be eligible to be effective upon filing pursuant
to Exchange Act Rule 19b-4(f)(6).\56\ One commenter believed that all
market data proposals should be subject to notice and comment, and that
the Commission should provide a 30-day comment period for such
proposals.\57\ In addition, the commenter cautioned that the rule
filing process should not become a ``rubberstamp'' of an exchange's
proposal.\58\ One commenter suggested that the Commission narrow its
delegation of authority with respect to proposed rule changes to
exclude proposals that have generated significant public comment.\59\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\56\ Baker Letter at 1-2; SIFMA III at 22; Bloomberg Letter at
6.
\57\ SIFMA III at 22.
\58\ SIFMA I at 2 n. 3.
\59\ NetCoalition III at 3-4.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
4. Importance of Depth-of-Book Data
One commenter maintained that because single-market depth-of-book
data products have significant advantages over consolidated top-of-book
products in terms of both speed and the depth of interest displayed,
many broker-dealers believe that it is prudent to purchase single-
market depth-of-book data to satisfy their best execution and
Regulation NMS order routing obligations.\60\ The commenter noted that
NYSE Arca has indicated in its advertising materials that its ArcaBook
data feed is approximately 60 times faster than the consolidated data
feeds and displays six times the liquidity within five cents of the
inside quote.\61\ The commenter also maintained that the NYSE has
linked its depth-of-book products to best execution by stating that
``NYSE Arca's market data products are designed to improve trade
execution.'' \62\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\60\ SIFMA III at 5-6. The commenter stated that depth-of-book
information has become more important because of the reduction in
liquidity at the inside quote and the increase in quote volatility
since decimalization, and because depth-of-book quotations are
likely to become more executable following the implementation of
Regulation NMS. SIFMA III at 12-13. Similarly, another commenter
maintained that, through Regulation NMS, the Commission ``has
imposed a system that requires access to depth-of-book
information.'' Schwab Letter at 5. Likewise, a commenter believed
that market participants require depth-of-book information to trade
effectively in decimalized markets. SIFMA IV at 8. See also
NetCoalition III at 5.
\61\ SIFMA III at 14 n. 24.
\62\ SIFMA IV at 12.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
One commenter argued that the central processors that distribute
consolidated data have little incentive to invest in modernizing their
operations.\63\ Another commenter believed that the disparity between
faster and more expensive depth-of-book proprietary data feeds and the
slower, less costly, and less valuable consolidated data feeds results
in a ``two-tiered structure with institutions having access to prices
not reasonably available to small investors * * *,'' circumstances that
the commenter believed ``recreate the informational advantage that once
existed on the physical floors of the open outcry markets.'' \64\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\63\ SIFMA III at 13.
\64\ Financial Services Roundtable Letter at 3. One commenter
believed that market participants who choose not to purchase depth-
of-book data will face the informational disadvantages that
Regulation NMS seeks to eliminate. NSX Letter at 2.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Another commenter believed that depth-of-book information should be
considered basic information for retail investors as well as
professional investors and that one goal of the National Market System
should be to assure that ``all investors * * * whether professional or
non-professional * * * have equal access to the same quality
information, at a reasonable price, and at the same time.'' \65\
Similarly, a commenter believed that retail investors require
quotations beyond the national best bid or offer to assess the quality
of the executions they receive.\66\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\65\ SIFMA IV at 13.
\66\ NetCoalition III at 5 n. 16.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
5. Lack of Competition in Market Data Pricing
Commenters argued that there are no effective competitive or market
forces that limit what an exchange may charge for its depth-of-book
data.\67\ Although one commenter acknowledged the argument that
competition in the market for liquidity and transactions could serve as
a constraint on what exchanges may charge for their data products, the
commenter believed that the consolidations of the NYSE with Archipelago
and Nasdaq with BRUT and INET have limited this constraint.\68\ The
commenter also asserted that competition in the market for order
execution is not the same as competition in the market for market data,
and that an economic analysis must consider the market for market data
from the consumer's perspective.\69\ Because proprietary market data is
a ``sole-source product,'' the commenter believed that no market forces
operate on the transaction between an exchange and the consumer of its
data.\70\ The commenter believed that the unique characteristics of the
market for market data--including increased market concentration and
market participants' obligation to purchase sole-source proprietary
market data to trade effectively--resulted in a ``classic economic
market failure * * * that requires comprehensive regulatory
intervention to ensure `fair and reasonable' prices.'' \71\ Similarly,
another commenter maintained that,
[[Page 74775]]
with respect to market data that is exclusive to an exchange, ``[t]here
is no way for competitive forces to produce market-driven or `fair and
reasonable' prices required by the Exchange Act * * *.'' \72\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\67\ NetCoalition III at 9; SIFMA III at 16-17; SIFMA IV at 5.
\68\ SIFMA III at 17.
\69\ SIFMA IV at 5. See also NetCoalition III at 2.
\70\ SIFMA IV at 5.
\71\ SIFMA IV at 8. The commenter believed that Congress
envisioned the Commission regulating exclusive processors in a
manner similar to the way in which public utilities are regulated.
SIFMA I at 5.
\72\ NetCoalition III at 2.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Other commenters believed that an exchange has a monopoly position
as the exclusive processor of its proprietary data that ``creates a
serious potential for abusive pricing practices,'' \73\ and urged the
Commission to consider the lack of competition and the inability to
obtain market data from other sources.\74\ One commenter asserted that
``broker-dealers will * * * be forced to purchase market data at a
fixed and * * * arbitrary price'' until market data fees are
reformed.\75\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\73\ Schwab Letter at 6. See also Spencer Letter.
\74\ Citigroup Letter at 1. Similarly, a commenter believed that
``[u]nless checked by effective regulatory oversight * * * exchanges
have both the incentives and the power to charge whatever they can
for the market data over which they have exclusive control.'' SIFMA
III at 4. The commenter also asserted that ``[t]he lack of both
economic market forces and comprehensive oversight of exchanges as
the sole-source processors of market data * * * has allowed the
exchange to simply `name their prices' * * *.'' SIFMA IV at 2.
\75\ NSX Letter at 2.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
In addition, several commenters believed that the transformation of
most U.S. securities exchanges from not-for-profit membership
organizations to for-profit entities has eliminated an important
constraint on market data fees as the for-profit exchanges seek to
maximize value for their shareholders.\76\ In this regard, one
commenter explained that ``exchanges are beholden to their shareholders
to increase revenue, and market data is the revenue stream that holds
the greatest potential for doing so.'' \77\ Other commenters argued
that the advent of for-profit exchanges has eliminated the governance
checks on market data pricing that operated when exchange members--
broker-dealers who were obligated to purchase consolidated market
data--sat on the boards of the non-profit, member-owned exchanges.\78\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\76\ ABA Letter at 2-3; Financial Services Roundtable Letter at
2; Schwab Letter at 5; SIFMA III at 24.
\77\ Schwab Letter at 5. See also NetCoalition II at 4; SIFMA
III at 24; SIFMA IV at 2.
\78\ Financial Services Roundtable Letter at 2; NetCoalition II
at 4; SIFMA III at 15.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
6. Increase in Market Data Revenues
With respect to the increase in the NYSE Group's market data
revenues following its merger with Archipelago, one commenter stated
that ``NYSE Group's reported market data segment revenues totaled $57.5
million in the third quarter of 2006: Up 33.7% from the same three-
month period in 2005.'' \79\ According to the commenter, the NYSE Group
attributed its revenue growth in market data to the contribution of
NYSE Arca's operations following the completion of the merger between
the NYSE and Archipelago on March 7, 2006.\80\ The commenter maintained
that Nasdaq has experienced similar growth in its market data revenues
and that the exchanges ``propose to charge fees for a series of market
data products that, when multiplied by the number of potential
subscribers, are resulting in increased costs of doing business
totaling tens of millions of dollars per year for some individual firms
and hundreds of millions of dollars per year across the financial
markets.'' \81\ The commenter identified the current fees for
proprietary and consolidated market data products and claimed that
investors ultimately pay these fees.\82\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\79\ SIFMA III at 18-19 (citations omitted).
\80\ SIFMA III at 18 (citation omitted).
\81\ SIFMA III at 4.
\82\ SIFMA IV at 14 and Appendix A.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
7. Recommended Solutions
To address the issues raised by market data fees, the commenters
suggested several potential solutions. One commenter recommended that
the Commission adopt a specialized market data form for market data
rule proposals that would require a detailed justification of proposed
fee changes by the SROs.\83\ The commenter believed that the form
should, among other things, require an exchange to substantiate its
historical costs of producing market data, its current market data
revenues, how and why its costs have changed and the existing revenue
is no longer appropriate, how the fee would impact market participants,
how the revenues would be used, and the contract terms, system
specifications, and audit requirements that would be associated with
the proposed fee change.\84\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\83\ SIFMA III at 21-22.
\84\ SIFMA III at 21-22.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The commenter also believed that the contract terms governing the
use of market data should be included in market data rule filings and
subject to notice and comment.\85\ The commenter maintained that the
contract terms are effectively non-negotiable and that the compliance
costs associated with them may affect the efficiency and transparency
of the markets. Another commenter asserted that exchange market data
contracts limit the use and dissemination of the data provided under
the contracts, potentially impairing the flow and further analysis of
the information, and impose administrative and technological burdens on
firms.\86\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\85\ SIFMA III at 23.
\86\ Citigroup Letter at 2.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The commenters also suggested structural changes to address market
data issues, including requiring exchanges to place their market data
operations in a separate subsidiary and to make their raw market data
available to third parties on the same terms as they make the data
available to their market data subsidiary and to the independent
central processor.\87\ The commenters believed that this could
encourage competition in providing market data products and services
\88\ and create a mechanism for free market pricing.\89\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\87\ Bloomberg Letter at 4; Kanjorski Letter at 1; NetCoalition
I at 2; Schwab Letter at 7; SIFMA III at 24-25.
\88\ SIFMA III at 25.
\89\ Schwab Letter at 7.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Finally, the commenters suggested that the Commission increase the
quality and depth of the required consolidated quotation information to
allow retail investors to determine the prices at which their orders
will be executed and to observe pricing movements in the market.\90\
One commenter recommended that the Commission require exchanges to
consolidate and distribute their top and depth-of-book data, and that
the associated costs be paid by investors who act on the
information.\91\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\90\ Schwab Letter 5; SIFMA III at 25-26.
\91\ NSX Letter at 2. Other commenters endorse this
recommendation.NetCoalition III at 7, 13; SIFMA IV at 15.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
B. Commenters Supporting the Action by Delegated Authority
Several commenters who supported the approval of the Proposal by
delegated authority argued that the staff applied the correct legal
standard \92\ and that the broader policy questions raised by the
Petition should be addressed in the context of Commission rulemaking,
rather than in connection with a specific exchange market data
proposal.\93\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\92\ Amex Letter at 2; ISE Letter at 3; PHLX Letter at 2-3.
\93\ Amex Letter at 4; PHLX Letter at 8.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Several commenters rejected the assertion that a cost-based
standard is the correct standard for the Commission to apply in
reviewing market data fee proposals.\94\ In this regard, the commenters
distinguished between the standards applicable to ``core'' market data
(i.e., consolidated quotation and last sale data for U.S.-listed
equities) and the standards applicable to
[[Page 74776]]
proprietary market data products.\95\ One commenter maintained that the
Commission, in adopting Regulation NMS, authorized exchanges to
distribute market data outside of the national market system plans,
subject to the general fairness and nondiscrimination standards of Rule
603 of Regulation NMS, but ``otherwise [left] to free market forces the
determination of what information would be provided and at what
price.'' \96\ Another commenter, noting that the Commission
specifically considered and refrained from adopting the cost-based
standard that NetCoalition proposes, argued that NetCoalition's
approach ``would replace Regulation NMS * * * with a complex and
intrusive rate-making approach that is inconsistent with the goals of
the * * * [Exchange Act] and would be more costly than beneficial.''
\97\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\94\ Exchange Market Data Coalition Letter at 2; ISE Letter at
3; PHLXLetter at 4.
\95\ Amex Letter at 1; ISE Letter at 2-3; PHLX Letter at 4-5.
\96\ Amex Letter at 2. The commenter noted that exchange fees
also aresubject to the requirements of Section 6(b)(4) of the
Exchange Act. See also PHLX Letter at 7.
\97\ Exchange Market Data Coalition Letter at 2. One commenter
asserted that ``[a]pplying NetCoalition's proposed strict cost-based
fee analysis to every exchange market data rule filing is unworkable
and * * * is not required under the Act.'' ISE Letter at 3.
Similarly, noting that SROs must ensure that market data is not
corrupted by fraud or manipulation, another commenter believed that
it would be virtually impossible to identify the costs specifically
associated with the production of market data versus other SRO
functions. PHLX Letter at 6.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
One commenter disagreed with the assertion that an exchange
possesses monopoly pricing power with respect to its proprietary data
products. It contended that assertions concerning an exchange's
monopoly pricing power ``ignore * * * market reality and market
discipline. If any exchange attempts to charge excessive fees, there
simply will not be buyers for such products.'' \98\ Nasdaq noted that,
as of April 30, 2007, over 420,000 professional users purchased core
data, but less than 19,000 professional users purchased TotalView,
Nasdaq's proprietary depth-of-book order product.\99\ It concluded that
``[b]roker-dealers may claim they are required to purchase TotalView,
but their actions indicate otherwise.'' \100\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\98\ ISE Letter at 3. Similarly, another commenter noted that
the users of data will purchase data ``if it provides them value and
is priced reasonably.'' Amex Letter at 1.
\99\ Nasdaq Letter at 6.
\100\ Nasdaq Letter at 6.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The commenters emphasized that the exchanges face significant
competition in their efforts to attract order flow:
Exchanges compete not only with one another, but also with
broker-dealers that match customer orders within their own systems
and also with a proliferation of alternative trading systems
(``ATSs'') and electronic communications networks (``ECNs'') that
the Commission has also nurtured and authorized to execute trades in
any listed issue. As a result, market share of trading fluctuates
among execution facilities based on their ability to service the end
customer. The execution business is highly competitive and exhibits
none of the characteristics of a monopoly as suggested in the
NetCoalition Petition.\101\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\101\ Exchange Market Data Coalition Letter at 4.
Similarly, another commenter stated that ``the market for
proprietary data products is currently competitive and inherently
contestable because there is fierce competition for the inputs
necessary to the creation of proprietary data and strict pricing
discipline for the proprietary products themselves.'' \102\ It also
noted that market data ``is the totality of the information assets that
each Exchange creates by attracting order flow'' and emphasized that
``[i]t is in each Exchange's best interest to provide proprietary
information to investors to further their business objectives, and each
Exchange chooses how best to do that.'' \103\ Commenters stated that,
in the absence of a regulatory requirement to provide non-core market
data, it is necessary to provide a financial or other business
incentive for exchanges to make such data available.\104\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\102\ Nasdaq Letter at 7.
\103\ Id. at 3, 4.
\104\ Amex Letter at 1; ISE Letter at 2; PHLX Letter at 7.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
IV. NYSE Arca Responses to Commenters
A. Response to Commenters on Proposal
In its responses to commenters on the Proposal, the Exchange argued
that the Proposal establishes ``a framework for distributing data in
which all vendors and end users are permitted to receive and use the
Exchange's market data on equal, non-discriminatory terms.'' \105\ The
Exchange asserted that the proposed professional and non-professional
device fees for the NYSE Arca Data were fair and reasonable because
they ``are far lower than those already established--and approved by
the Commission--for similar products offered by other U.S. equity
exchanges and stock markets.'' \106\ In particular, the Exchange noted
that the proposed $15 per month device fee for each of the ArcaBook
data products is less than both the $60 per month and $70 per month
device fees that the NYSE and Nasdaq, respectively, charge for
comparable market data products.\107\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\105\ NYSE Arca Response I at 2.
\106\ Id.
\107\ NYSE Arca Response I at 2-3.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
With respect to its proposed fees, the Exchange noted, further,
that it had invested significantly in its ArcaBook products, including
making technological enhancements that allowed the Exchange to expand
capacity and improve processing efficiency as message traffic
increased, thereby reducing the latency associated with the
distribution of ArcaBook data.\108\ The Exchange stated that ``[i]n
determining to invest the resources necessary to enhance ArcaBook
technology, the Exchange contemplated that it would seek to charge for
the receipt and use of ArcaBook data.'' \109\ The Exchange also
emphasized the reasonableness of its proposed fee relative to other
comparable market data products, asserting, for example, that ``NYSE
Arca is at the inside price virtually as often as Nasdaq, yet the
proposed fee for ArcaBook is merely one-fifth of the TotalView fee.''
\110\ Moreover, it stated that its decision to commence charging for
ArcaBook data was based on its view that ``market data charges are a
particularly equitable means for funding a market's investment in
technology and its operations. In contrast with transaction,
membership, listing, regulatory and other SRO charges, market data
charges cause all consumers of a securities market's services,
including investors and market data vendors, to contribute.'' \111\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\108\ NYSE Arca Response II at 2.
\109\ Id. at 3.
\110\ Id.
\111\ Id. at 4.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The Exchange stated that it proposes to use the CTA and CQ Plan
contracts to govern the distribution of NYSE Arca Data and that it was
not amending the terms of these existing contracts or imposing
restrictions on the use or display of its data beyond those that are
currently set forth in the contracts.\112\ Further, the Exchange
specifically noted that these contracts do not prohibit a broker-dealer
from making its own data available outside of the CTA and CQ
Plans.\113\ Finally, the Exchange argued that by using this current
structure, it believes that the administrative burdens on firms and
vendors should be low.\114\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\112\ NYSE Arca Response I at 3.
\113\ Id. at n. 12 and accompanying text.
\114\ Id. at 5.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
B. Response to Commenters on Petition
In its response to commenters on the Petition, the Exchange argued
that recent market-based solutions have mooted the concerns expressed
in the
[[Page 74777]]
Petition regarding the affordability of market data for internet
portals.\115\ In particular, the Exchange noted that the NYSE recently
submitted a proposed rule change for a market data product that would
provide unlimited real-time last sale prices to vendors for a fixed
monthly fee (``NYSE Internet Proposal'').\116\ The Exchange stated that
this NYSE Internet Proposal ``would meet the needs of internet portals
and add to the number of choices that are available to intermediaries
and investors for their receipt of real-time prices.'' \117\ The
Exchange asserted that the NYSE Internet Proposal ``provides a
significant benefit to investors'' since ``it adds to the data-access
alternatives available to them and improves the quality, timeliness and
affordability of data they can receive over the internet.'' \118\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\115\ NYSE Arca Response III at 5-6.
\116\ See id. at 5.
\117\ NYSE Arca Response III at 5.
\118\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The Exchange also reiterated the argument that the proposed market
data fees meet the statutory standards for such fees under the Exchange
Act.\119\ The Exchange argued that the fees represent an equitable
allocation of fees and charges since they ``represent the first time
that [the Exchange] has established a fee that a person or entity other
than an [Exchange] member or listed company must pay'' and are being
imposed ``on those who use the facilities of [the Exchange] but do not
otherwise contribute to [the Exchange's] operating costs.'' \120\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\119\ Id. at 11.
\120\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The Exchange argued that the proposed market data fees are not
``unreasonably discriminatory'' since ``all professional subscribers
are subject to the same fees and all nonprofessional subscribers are
subject to the same fees.'' \121\ The Exchange noted that the only
discrimination that occurs is the ``reasonable'' distinction that would
require professional subscribers to pay higher fees than
nonprofessional subscribers.\122\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\121\ Id.
\122\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The Exchange asserted that the fees are fair and reasonable
because: (1) ``They compare favorably to the level of fees that other
U.S. markets and the CTA and Nasdaq/UTP Plans impose for comparable
products''; (2) ``the quantity and quality of data NYSE Arca includes
in Arca Book compares favorably to the data that other markets include
in their market data products''; and (3) ``the fees will enable NYSE
Arca to recover the resources that NYSE Arca devoted to the technology
necessary to produce Arca Book data.'' \123\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\123\ Id. at 11-12.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The Exchange also rejected the Petitioner's assertion that the
Exchange acted ``arbitrarily or capriciously'' by using a comparison of
similar market data fees in setting the level of the proposed
fees.\124\ The Exchange noted that in addition to studying ``what other
markets charge for comparable products,'' the Exchange also considered:
(1) The needs of those entities that would likely purchase the Arca
Book data; (2) the ``contribution that revenues from Arca Book Fees
would make toward replacing the revenues that NYSE Arca stands to lose
as a result of the removal of the NQDS service from the Nasdaq/UTP
Plan''; (3) ``the contribution that revenues accruing from Arca Book
Fees would make toward NYSE Arca's market data business''; (4) the
contribution that revenues accruing from Arca Book Fees would make
toward meeting the overall costs of NYSE Arca's operations''; (5)
``projected losses to NYSE Arca's business model and order flow that
might result from marketplace resistance to Arca Book Fees''; and (6)
``the fact that Arca Book is primarily a product for market
professionals, who have access to other sources of market data and who
will purchase Arca Book only if they determine that the perceived
benefits outweigh the cost.'' \125\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\124\ Id. at 12.
\125\ Id. at 12-13.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The Exchange also rejected the Petitioner's assertion that all
proposed market data fees must be subjected to a rigorous cost-based
analysis.\126\ The Exchange noted that the Petitioner ``is able to cite
only one instance'' that supports such an assertion.\127\ The Exchange
also noted that Petitioner ``fails to mention that a significant
portion of the industry'' expressed opposition to a cost-based approach
to analyzing market data fees in respo