Antidumping Methodologies: Market Economy Inputs, Expected Non-Market Economy Wages, Duty Drawback; and Request for Comments, 61716-61724 [E6-17376]
Download as PDF
61716
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 202 / Thursday, October 19, 2006 / Notices
Governments, which terminated the
Request for an Extraordinary Challenge
Committee, this Binational Panel review
is completed effective October 12, 2006.
The panel appointed to this review has
been dismissed in accordance with the
Rules of Procedure for Article 1904
Binational Panel Review, effective
October 12, 2006.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
Caratina L. Alston, United States
Secretary, NAFTA Secretariat, Suite
2061, 14th and Constitution Avenue,
Washington, DC 20230, (202) 482–5438.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: Pursuant
to the negotiated settlement agreement
between the United States and Canadian
Governments, the United States
withdrew the request for an
Extraordinary Challenge Committee
Review, which was filed on April 27,
2006. The negotiated settlement became
effective on October 12, 2006. The
Extraordinary Challenge Committee was
to review the decisions of the Binational
Panel that reviewed the final
determination and remand
determinations by the United States
Department of Commerce in ‘‘The
Matter of Certain Softwood Lumber
Products from Canada: Final Affirmative
Countervailing Duty Determination,
Secretariat File No. USA–CDA–2002–
1904–03’’. Therefore, on the basis of the
negotiated settlement between the
United States and Canada, the panel
review was completed and the panelists
discharged from their duties effective
October 12, 2006.
Dated: October 13, 2006.
Caratina L. Alston,
United States Secretary, NAFTA Secretariat.
[FR Doc. E6–17405 Filed 10–18–06; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 3510–GT–P
DEPARTMENT OF COMMERCE
International Trade Administration
Antidumping Methodologies: Market
Economy Inputs, Expected Non–
Market Economy Wages, Duty
Drawback; and Request for Comments
Import Administration,
International Trade Administration,
Department of Commerce.
ACTION: Announcement of Change in
Methodology, Request for Comment
cprice-sewell on PROD1PC66 with NOTICES
AGENCY:
SUMMARY: This notice addresses three
methodologies of the Department of
Commerce (‘‘the Department’’) in
antidumping proceedings. First, the
Department is revising its approach
concerning the use of market economy
inputs in the calculation of normal
value in antidumping proceedings
VerDate Aug<31>2005
14:50 Oct 18, 2006
Jkt 211001
involving non–market economy
(‘‘NME’’) countries. Specifically, the
Department is revising its approach
concerning cases where an NME
producer sources an input from both
market economy suppliers and from
within the NME. Second, the
Department is revising its methodology
for calculating expected NME wages in
antidumping proceedings involving
NME countries. Third, the Department
is requesting comments on its approach
concerning the calculation of duty
drawback adjustments to export price in
antidumping proceedings when a
respondent producer obtains an input
both from domestic and foreign sources.
On this latter issue, the Department is
seeking comments on the methodology
that should be used when the producer
receives duty drawback on certain
exports containing the input but not on
other exports containing the input.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
Lawrence Norton with regard to market
economy inputs, Shauna Lee–Alaia with
regard to expected NME wages, and
John Kalitka with regard to duty
drawback, Office of Policy, Import
Administration, U.S. Department of
Commerce, 14th Street and Constitution
Avenue, NW, Washington DC, 20230,
202–482–1579, 202–482–2793, or 202–
482–2730, respectively.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION:
Issue One: Market Economy Inputs
Background
In antidumping proceedings involving
NME countries, the Department
calculates normal value by valuing the
NME producer’s factors of production,
to the extent possible, using prices from
a market economy that is at a
comparable level of economic
development and that is also a
significant producer of comparable
merchandise. The goal of this surrogate
factor valuation is to use the ‘‘best
available information’’ to determine
normal value. See section 773(c)(1) of
the Tariff Act of 1930, as amended (‘‘the
Act’’); see also Shangdong Huraong
General Corp. v. United States, 159 F.
Supp. 2d 714, 719 (CIT 2001). When an
NME producer purchases inputs from
market economy suppliers and pays in
a market economy currency, the
Department normally uses the average
actual price paid by the NME producer
for these inputs to value the input in
question, where possible. See 19 CFR
351.408(c)(1); see also Final
Determination of Sales at Less Than
Fair Value: Oscillating Fans and Ceiling
Fans from the People’s Republic of
China, 56 FR 55271, 55274–75 (October
25, 1991). When a portion of the input
PO 00000
Frm 00011
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
is purchased from a market economy
supplier and the remainder from a non–
market economy supplier, the
Department will normally use the price
paid for the input sourced from market
economy suppliers to value all of the
input,1 provided that the volume of the
market economy input as a share of total
purchases from all sources is
‘‘meaningful,’’ a term used in the
Preamble to the Regulations but which
is interpreted by the Department on a
case–by-case basis. See Antidumping
Duties; Countervailing Duties; Final
Rule, 62 FR 27296, 27366 (May 19,
1997) (‘‘Final Rule’’); see also
Shakeproof v. United States, 268 F.3d
1376, 1382 (Fed. Cir. 2001)
(‘‘Shakeproof’’). Such market economy
input purchases must also constitute
arms–length, bona fide sales. See
Shakeproof, 268 F.3d at 1382–83.
Additionally, the Department
disregards market economy input
purchases when there is evidence that
the prices for such inputs may be
distorted or when the facts of a
particular case otherwise demonstrate
that market economy input purchase
prices are not the best available
information. For example, the
Department disregards all input values
it has reason to believe or suspect might
be dumped or subsidized. See, e.g.,
China National Machinery Import &
Export Corporation v. United States, 293
F. Supp. 2d 1334 (CIT 2003), as aff’d per
curiam 04 Fed. Appx. 183 (Federal
Circuit, July 9, 2004). The Department
has also disregarded the prices of inputs
that could not possibly have been used
in the production of subject
merchandise during the period of
investigation or review. See, e.g., Final
Determination of Sales at Less Than
Fair Value: Certain Frozen and Canned
Warmwater Shrimp from the Socialist
Republic of Vietnam, 69 FR 71005, and
accompanying Issues and Decision
Memorandum, at comment 8 (December
8, 2004) (‘‘Shrimp’’). The Department
has further rejected purchase prices
from market economies when the input
in question was produced within an
NME. See Final Determination of Sales
at Less Than Fair Value: Polyethylene
Retail Carrier Bags from the People’s
Republic of China, 69 FR 34125 and
accompanying Issues and Decision
Memorandum, at comment 4 (June 18,
2004).
The Department published on May
26, 2005, August 11, 2005, and March
21, 2006, three notices in the Federal
Register requesting comment on its
market economy inputs methodology in
NME cases (70 FR 30418, 70 FR 46816,
1 See
E:\FR\FM\19OCN1.SGM
19 CFR 351.408(c)(1).
19OCN1
cprice-sewell on PROD1PC66 with NOTICES
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 202 / Thursday, October 19, 2006 / Notices
and 71 FR 14176, respectively). In these
notices, the Department requested
comment on various proposals
concerning the Department’s approach
in cases in which NME firms purchase
a portion of a given input from a market
economy and source the remainder
domestically. In such instances, the
Department must make a case–specific
determination as to what the best
available information is for valuing the
input: the market–economy purchase
price or another surrogate value. The
guidance given in the Department’s
regulations, as described above, is
‘‘normally’’ to use the prices paid for the
market economy portion of the input to
value the entire input. While the
regulations do not elaborate as to what
circumstances are ‘‘normal,’’ the
Preamble states that the Department will
disregard market economy purchases if
the volume involved is not
‘‘meaningful.’’ In response to the
Department’s March 21, 2006 request for
comment, the Department received
comments in April 2006 from the
following six interested parties: (1) the
Committee to Support U.S. Trade Laws
(‘‘CSUSTL’’); (2) the United States Steel
Corporation (‘‘U.S. Steel’’); (3) the
American Furniture Manufacturers
Committee (‘‘Furniture Committee’’); (4)
Stewart and Stewart; (5) the Ministry of
Commerce of the People’s Republic of
China (‘‘PRC MOFCOM’’); and (6) Trade
Pacific.
The Department requested comment
on its market economy inputs practice
for two reasons. First, the undefined
nature of what constitutes a
‘‘meaningful’’ quantity of market
economy purchases implies that the
Department must currently make case–
specific decisions as to whether to
accept market economy purchase prices
to value inputs. This creates
unpredictability as to what values
would ultimately be used in the
dumping calculation. Parties can
advocate accepting or disregarding the
use of market economy purchase prices
in individual cases, but do not have a
concrete framework for doing so.
Indeed, parties representing NME
exporters have argued that market
economy purchase prices nearly always
constitute the ‘‘best available
information’’ to use in the Department’s
dumping calculations, whereas parties
representing domestic industry have
argued that market economy purchases
should almost never be used to value
the portion of an input that was sourced
domestically within the NME. This
conflicting understanding as to when
market economy purchases should be
used to value an entire input is also
VerDate Aug<31>2005
14:50 Oct 18, 2006
Jkt 211001
evident in the submissions the
Department received in response to its
requests for comment on its market
economy inputs approach. Absent an
announced threshold as to what
quantities are generally considered to be
‘‘meaningful,’’ parties would continue
to argue this issue without the benefit of
any clear guidance from the
Department.
The Department’s second reason for
requesting comment on its market
economy inputs approach was its
concern that it may, in some cases, have
used market economy input purchase
prices to value an entire input even
when these prices may not have been
the ‘‘best available information.’’ While
the Department has not had a specific
threshold for what constitutes a
‘‘meaningful’’ quantity, the Department
is concerned that accepting a market
economy input value when the portion
sourced from a market economy is too
low may not constitute the best
available information, particularly when
no additional scrutiny is applied to
ensure that the market economy price is
representative of what the total price
would have been had the firm
purchased solely from market economy
suppliers. This is a potential problem
because the Department has greater
confidence that the market economy
purchase price is reflective of total
purchase values of the input (and, thus,
that it represents the ‘‘best available
information’’) when the proportion of
the total volume of the input that is
sourced from market economies is
higher. To take an extreme example,
where an NME exporter purchases all of
a given input from a market economy
supplier, the Department can be
confident that this price reflects total
purchase value of the input. Conversely,
if an NME firm purchases a tiny
quantity of the input from market
economy suppliers and sources the rest
domestically, the Department may have
little or no confidence that this purchase
price reflects the NME firm’s overall
purchases of the input. There might be
numerous factors that could easily
distort a single, small volume market
economy purchase price, for example:
sample sales, ‘‘bundling’’ of the
purchase at a low price with other
purchases at higher prices, limited
quantities available on the market at an
unusually low price, or brief plunges in
the market price for the input. Of
course, even a single purchase of an
input might also, depending on the
facts, be representative of what an NME
exporter’s purchases would have been
had it sourced all of the input in
question from the market economy
PO 00000
Frm 00012
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
61717
source throughout the period of
investigation or review. As a general
rule, however, the Department typically
rejects purchases of small quantities
because ‘‘insignificant’’ quantities are
less likely to be representative of a
company’s cost of sourcing the entire
input. See Final Determination of Sales
at Less Than Fair Value and Negative
Final Determination of Critical
Circumstances: Certain Color Television
Receivers from the People’s Republic of
China, 69 FR 20594 and accompanying
Issues and Decision Memorandum, at
comment 12 (April 16, 2004).
This was the intended reasoning in
the Preamble to the Regulations, which
states that the Department ‘‘would not
rely on the price paid by an NME
producer to a market economy supplier
if the quantity of the input purchased
was insignificant. Because the amounts
purchased from the market economy
supplier must be meaningful, this
requirement goes some way in
addressing the commenter’s concern
that the NME producer may not be able
to fulfill all of its needs at that price.’’
See Final Rule, 62 at 27366. By
announcing a basic threshold of what
constitutes such a ‘‘meaningful’’
quantity, and by making it high enough
to reduce the chance of using a distorted
price, without setting it too high to
routinely prevent the use of market
economy input prices, the Department
can give greater effect to the intent of
the regulations and improve its market
economy inputs practice, to the benefit
of all parties. This was the reasoning
behind some of the proposals the
Department put forward in its Federal
Register notices soliciting comment on
its methodology in this area. This
decision, along with a discussion of the
relevant public comments, is set forth
below.
Statement of Policy
Drawing on the many submissions the
Department has received in response to
its requests for comment, the
Department is now revising its
methodology. While the Department
may still consider amending its
regulations to remove the regulatory
requirement that the Department
‘‘normally’’ use market economy input
prices to value the entire amount of
such inputs, the Department is now
establishing clearer guidance as to the
circumstances in which it will accept
market economy purchase prices to
value an entire input. The Department
is now instituting a rebuttable
presumption that market economy input
prices are the best available information
for valuing an entire input when the
total volume of the input purchased
E:\FR\FM\19OCN1.SGM
19OCN1
61718
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 202 / Thursday, October 19, 2006 / Notices
cprice-sewell on PROD1PC66 with NOTICES
from all market economy sources during
the period of investigation or review
exceeds 33 percent of the total volume
of the input purchased from all sources
during the period. In these cases, unless
case–specific facts provide adequate
grounds to rebut the Department’s
presumption, the Department will use
the weighted–average market economy
purchase price to value the entire input.
Alternatively, when the volume of an
NME firm’s purchases from market
economy suppliers as a percentage of its
total volume of purchases during the
period of review is below 33 percent,
but where these purchases are otherwise
valid and meet the Department’s
existing conditions (described in the
Background section above), the
Department will weight–average the
weighted–average market economy
purchase price with an appropriate
surrogate value according to their
respective shares of the total volume of
purchases, unless case–specific facts
provide adequate grounds to rebut the
presumption. In determining whether
market economy purchases meet this 33
percent threshold, the Department will
compare the volume that the producer
purchased from market economy
sources during the period of
investigation or review with the
respondent’s total purchases during the
period.2 When a firm has made market
economy input purchases that may have
been dumped or subsidized, are not
bona fide, or are otherwise not
acceptable for use in a dumping
calculation, the Department will
exclude them from the numerator of the
ratio to ensure a fair determination of
whether valid market economy
purchases meet the 33 percent
threshold. This addresses the comment
by Trade Pacific that the Department
explain how it intends to calculate
whether a given quantity of purchases
meets the threshold, and ensures a fair
comparison between acceptable market
economy purchases and total purchases
of the input during the period of
investigation or review. Morever,
because this 33 percent threshold
constitutes a rebutable presumption,
parties will have an opportunity to
2 Notwithstanding the determination the
Department reached in Shrimp, at comment 8, the
Department will examine if and when the inputs
were used in the production process when casespecific conditions demand it. Unless there are
case-specific reasons to examine other criteria, the
Department will base its decision on whether to
accept market economy input purchases to value
the entire input on the relative share of market
economy purchases during the period of
investigation or review to total purchases during the
period of investigation or review.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
14:50 Oct 18, 2006
Jkt 211001
demonstrate that case–specific facts
outweigh the presumption.
The practice described above is
consistent with our current regulations
directing the Department to ‘‘normally’’
use market economy input prices to
value an entire input. While, as
discussed above, the term ‘‘normally’’ is
not defined in the regulations, it has
been established in both the Preamble
and through the Department’s long–
standing case precedent that the
Department may decline to accept
market economy purchases to value an
input when the volume involved is
insignificant. See, e.g., Preliminary
Results of Administrative Review:
Automotive Glass Windshields from
China, 70 FR 24373, 24380 (May 9,
2005) (‘‘Windshields’’) (‘‘{w}here the
quantity of the input purchased from
market–economy suppliers was
insignificant, the Department will not
rely on the price paid by an NME
producer to a market–economy supplier
because it cannot have confidence that
a company could fulfill all its needs at
that price.’’). Windshields is
representative of the Department’s
consistent standard that it will rely on
market economy purchases to value an
entire input only when the share of the
input sourced from market economy
suppliers, relative to the total volume
purchased, is high enough that the
Department has confidence that the
market economy purchase price is
reflective of the firm’s total purchases of
the input.
Accordingly, the Department’s
decision to introduce a flexible 33
percent threshold represents an
extension of its previous practice. This
standard of 33 percent is consistent with
a threshold that the Department has
defended, and the Court has upheld, as
constituting a ‘‘meaningful’’ quantity in
a prior case. See Shakeproof, 268 F.3d
at 1382–83. However, the Department is
now announcing what will generally
constitute a ‘‘meaningful’’ or
‘‘significant’’ quantity, as opposed to
making this determination on a strictly
case–specific basis and without general
guidance. Establishing a proportional,
rather than absolute, threshold is also
consistent with the logic described in
Windshields, because the decision of
whether to accept market economy
input purchases to value an entire input
rests on whether market economy
purchases are reflective of what the total
price would have been had the firm
purchased solely from market economy
suppliers.
Some commenters (including PRC
MOFCOM) have argued that the
Department’s proposed policy
statements provide solutions to what are
PO 00000
Frm 00013
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
only theoretical problems. These parties
argue that even if ‘‘bundling,’’ price
fluctuations or other factors that could
distort market economy purchases exist,
they have not been shown to be a
problem in past cases and so there is no
need for a remedy. The Department
disagrees with this assertion. The
Department cannot be privy to the
circumstances governing every purchase
of market economy inputs, nor can it be
expected to conduct an analysis of each
input market to see if given sales were
representative of what the total price
would have been had the firm
purchased solely from market economy
suppliers. Instead, the Department has
always relied on the quantity of the
input sourced from market economies as
a proxy to gauge its relative confidence
that the market economy purchase price
is indeed reflective of the total volume
of the input. The only difference is that
the Department is now announcing a
threshold, rather than making
exclusively case–specific decisions.
On this point, PRC MOFCOM and
others have argued that the Department
should not establish a ‘‘bright line’’
threshold, that any threshold is
arbitrary, and that the Department
already has sufficient discretion to
disregard market economy purchases
that are not legitimate or bona fide. As
described above, however, the
Department is not introducing a rigid,
‘‘bright line’’ threshold, but rather a
threshold that is amenable to
interpretation in the light of case–
specific facts and circumstances.
Moreover, this threshold is not arbitrary,
but is carefully crafted to balance two
competing concerns; i.e. to ensure that
market economy purchases are
reflective of total purchases without
contravening the regulatory requirement
to ‘‘normally’’ accept market economy
purchase prices to value an entire input
when they are available.
In response to the Department’s
proposal to weight–average the market
economy purchase price with a
surrogate value when the share of
market economy purchases falls below
the Department’s flexible threshold,
PRC MOFCOM argued that there can be
only one single source of the ‘‘best
available information,’’ and if the
market economy purchase price
constitutes the best information for
valuing the portion of the input sourced
from market economy countries, it must
also constitute the best information for
valuing the entire input. The
Department disagrees with this
assertion, and considers that the ‘‘best
available information’’ in cases in which
a respondent purchases a given input
both domestically and from market
E:\FR\FM\19OCN1.SGM
19OCN1
cprice-sewell on PROD1PC66 with NOTICES
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 202 / Thursday, October 19, 2006 / Notices
economy sources may be, depending on
the circumstances, a weighted–average
of a surrogate value and a market
economy purchase price. The fact that a
given price is valid for a (relatively
small) portion of the input in question
does not necessarily mean that it is
representative of the firm’s total
purchases of the input. While market
economy input purchase prices present
a valid price for the market economy
purchases that an NME firm actually
made, and the Department will use
these data, when possible, to value the
portion of the input purchased from
market economy sources, these prices
may not always be the best available
information for valuing the portion of
the input produced within the NME.
When the Department cannot be
confident that this price is
representative, however, if the price is
otherwise valid (as in being bona fide,
not subsidized, etc.), weight–averaging
an appropriate surrogate value with the
market economy purchase price would
be the most accurate valuation of the
input.
Other parties (including U.S. Steel,
Stewart and Stewart, and CSUSTL)
argue that except in rare cases, the
Department should never accept market
economy input purchases to value the
portion of the input sourced
domestically within the NME. Such a
policy would contradict the applicable
regulation, which clearly directs the
Department to ‘‘normally’’ use market
economy input purchases to value the
entire input, even if the market
economy purchases formed only a
portion of an NME firm’s total
purchases of the input. The Department
may consider a regulatory change in the
future to grant it greater discretion in
this area. Nevertheless, the Department
disagrees with the assertion that market
economy inputs never constitute the
‘‘best available information’’ just as it
disagrees that these purchases always
do so. Whether the best available
information to value the NME–produced
portion of the input is the price of the
firm’s market economy input purchases
or another surrogate value is a decision
that should guided by the relative shares
of the two types of purchases, as well as
by case–specific facts. U.S. Steel argues
that ‘‘establishing a bright line threshold
for market economy input purchases
(i.e., more than 33 percent) would
encourage respondents to manipulate
the results so as to favorably affect the
calculation of their dumping margins.’’
The Department does not agree that a
change in respondents’ behavior as a
result of this policy, by itself, amounts
to ‘‘manipulation.’’ Moreover, it is the
VerDate Aug<31>2005
14:50 Oct 18, 2006
Jkt 211001
Department’s view that requiring
parties, in most cases, to meet a 33
percent threshold actually reduces the
opportunity for manipulation.
The Department’s flexible percentage
threshold of 33 percent for accepting
market economy purchase prices to
value an entire input will improve the
predictability and accuracy of the
Department’s analysis, while continuing
to meet the Department’s regulatory
requirement to ‘‘normally’’ use market
economy purchases to value inputs
when they are available. Predictability
will be improved because parties will
have a clearer idea of when the
Department will accept market economy
purchase prices to value an entire input.
The Department will be able to calculate
more accurate dumping margins,
because the threshold sets a reasonable
ratio of the market economy–sourced
portion to that produced in the NME so
that the Department can be more
confident in the representativeness of
the market economy purchase prices.
However, this threshold is also not set
so high that it would contradict the
regulatory guidance on this issue.
Finally, the fact that this threshold
represents a rebuttable presumption
means that it will be flexible, allowing
the Department to take into account any
case–specific facts that may arise.
The approach detailed above will take
effect for all segments of NME
proceedings that are initiated after
publication of this notice in the Federal
Register.
Issue Two: Expected NME Wages
Background
With regard to its calculation of
expected NME wages, the Department
stated in its November 17, 2004 final
determination in the antidumping duty
investigation of sales at less than fair
value regarding Wooden Bedroom
Furniture from the People’s Republic of
China, that it would ‘‘invite comments
from the general public on this matter
in a proceeding separate from the
(Furniture) investigation.’’ Final
Determination of Sales at Less Than
Fair Value: Wooden Bedroom Furniture
From the People’s Republic of China, 69
FR 67313 and accompanying Issues and
Decision Memorandum, at comment 23
(November 17, 2004). On June 30, 2005,
the Department published a detailed
description of its methodology for the
calculation of expected NME wages and
a request for comment. See Expected
Non–Market Economy Wages: Request
for Comment on Calculation
Methodology, 70 FR 37761 (June 30,
2005) (‘‘Wage Rate FR’’). The
Department received comments on
PO 00000
Frm 00014
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
61719
August 1, 2005, from the following six
interested parties: (1) CSUSTL; (2)
Grunfeld, Desiderio, Lebowitz,
Silverman & Klestadt (‘‘Grunfeld’’); (3)
Lacquer Craft Manufacturing Company,
Ltd.; (4) Dorbest Limited; (5) PRC
MOFCOM; and (6) the Ministry of Trade
of the Socialist Republic of Vietnam
(‘‘VN Ministry of Trade’’).
The Department’s expected NME
wages are currently calculated each year
in two steps. First, the relationship
between hourly wage rates (obtained
from the International Labor
Organization’s (‘‘ILO’’) Yearbook of
Labour Statistics, relying on data that
has been reported within the six-year
period described below) and per–capita
gross national income (‘‘GNI’’) (obtained
from the World Bank) from market–
economy countries (the ‘‘basket of
countries’’) is estimated using an
ordinary least squares (‘‘OLS’’)
regression analysis. Second, the GNI of
each of the countries designated by the
Department as an NME is applied to the
regression, which yields an expected
hourly wage rate for each NME. For
further information, see Wage Rate FR.
PRC MOFCOM and the other
interested parties (excluding CSUSTL)
(‘‘PRC MOFCOM et al.’’) argued that
when the Department is valuing any
factor of production, including labor,
the Department is obliged to use data
from economically comparable
countries and that the inclusion of
countries not considered economically
comparable is in contravention of our
statute, citing 19 U.S.C. § 1677b(c)(4)
and Antidumping Duties;
Countervailing Duties, Part II, 62 FR
27296, 27367 (May 19, 1997) (‘‘Final
Rule’’). Finally, PRC MOFCOM et al.
asserted that the Department’s original
intention was to limit the regression
analysis to economically comparable
countries, citing Antidumping Duties;
Countervailing Duties Part II, 61 FR
7308 (February 27, 1996) (‘‘Proposed
Rule’’).
Accordingly, these parties proposed
that the Department revert to its former
practice of valuing direct labor using a
surrogate wage rate from a surrogate
country selected in each individual
proceeding, or an average of the wage
rates for the countries designated by the
Department as economically comparable
to the NME at the outset of each
proceeding. Alternatively, some parties
proposed that the Department should
estimate the relationship between wage
rates and per–capita GNI only for
countries that are economically
comparable to the NME country in
question, defined by either the Import
Administration’s Office of Policy or by
the World Bank’s national income
E:\FR\FM\19OCN1.SGM
19OCN1
61720
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 202 / Thursday, October 19, 2006 / Notices
cprice-sewell on PROD1PC66 with NOTICES
classifications. These parties asserted
that the inclusion of non–comparable
countries is both distortive and contrary
to the Department’s statutory directive
to use ‘‘economically comparable’’
surrogate values.
Alternatively, acknowledging that the
Department has a stated preference for
more data when valuing labor, these
parties proposed that the Department
expand its basket of countries to include
all countries for which the required data
are available.
Finally, some parties argued that the
Department should use a generalized
least squares (‘‘GLS’’) methodology for
its regression analysis in order to
account for heteroscedasticity in the
data set.
CSUSTL argued that the Department
is required to value all factors of
production for a given respondent, and
must therefore capture all labor costs
experienced by the respondent.
Accordingly, CSUSTL proposed that the
Department change its practice to rely
on ‘‘labor cost’’ figures from Chapter 6
of the ILO’s Yearbook of Labour
Statistics or, failing that, that the
Department should only use data from
Chapter 5 that captures ‘‘employee
earnings’’ rather than both earnings and
wages. CSUSTL also noted that in order
to capture all factors of production and
other costs, the Department’s
calculation of surrogate financial ratios
must be adjusted according to the labor
cost elements that are included in the
Department’s expected NME wage rates.
Statement of Policy
Section 733(c) of the Act provides that
the Department will value the factors of
production in an NME using the best
available information regarding the
value of such factors in a market
economy country or countries
considered to be appropriate by the
administering authority. The statute
only requires that when valuing the
factors of production, the Department
utilize, to the extent possible, the prices
or costs of factors of production in one
or more market economy countries that
are at a level of comparable economic
development. See Section 733(c)(4) of
the Act.
While surrogate values for other
factors of production are selected from
a single surrogate country, the
Department determined in its Final Rule
that it would be more accurate to base
estimated labor values on data from
many countries, stating that ‘‘more data
is better than less data, and that
averaging of multiple data points (or
regression analysis) should lead to more
accurate results in valuing any factor of
production. However, it is only for labor
VerDate Aug<31>2005
14:50 Oct 18, 2006
Jkt 211001
that we have a relatively consistent and
complete database covering many
countries.’’ See Final Rule at 62 FR
27367.
Accordingly, section 351.408(c)(3) of the
Department’s regulations provides that:
For labor, the Secretary will use regression–
based rates reflective of the observed
relationship between wages and national
income in market economy countries.
The Secretary will calculate the wage
rate to be applied in nonmarket economy
proceedings each year. The calculation
will be based on current data, and will
be made available to the public.
19 CFR 351.408 (c)(3).
The Department’s regulations
concerning the valuation of labor were
promulgated as part of a public notice
and comment process. In the Proposed
Rule the Department explained the
benefits of a wage rate derived from a
regression analysis, which include
fairness and predictability. The
Proposed Rule states:
Moreover, use of this average wage rate
will contribute to both the fairness and
the predictability of NME proceedings.
By avoiding the variability in results
depending on which economically
comparable country happens to be
selected as the surrogate, the results are
much fairer to all parties. To enhance
predictability, the average wage to be
applied in any NME proceeding will be
calculated by the Department each year,
based on the most recently available
data, and will be available to any
interested party.
See Proposed Rule, at 7345.
PRC MOFCOM et. al.’s comment that
the Department should abandon its
regression–based calculation of
expected NME wage rates in favor of the
use of a single surrogate value for wage
rates would contravene the
Department’s regulations, which direct
the Department to use regression–based
labor rates. In addition, as the
Department noted in the Proposed Rule,
while there is a strong positive
correlation between wage rates and GNI,
there is also variation in the wage rates
of comparable market economies. For
example, the Department’s November
2005 regression illustrates that the
observed hourly wage rates for market
economy countries with national
incomes below US$1,000 ranged from
US$0.23 to US$0.94. See https://
ia.ita.doc.gov/wages/03wages/110805–
2003–Tables/03wages–110805.html.
Therefore, if the Department adopted
this suggestion in a proceeding
involving an NME country with a GNI
under US$1,000, values for labor might
range from US$0.23 to US$0.94,
depending on which economically
comparable country is selected as the
surrogate. See Proposed Rule at 7345.
PO 00000
Frm 00015
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
The Department is able to avoid this
variability through the regression–based
methodology for estimating wage rates
due to the availability of reliable wage
rate data and the consistent relationship
over time between wage rates and GNI.
The Department relies upon what is, in
essence, an average wage rate, indexed
to each NME’s level of economic
development via its GNI. Under the
Department’s regression methodology,
the value for labor will be the same in
every proceeding involving a given
NME. This enhances the fairness and
predictability of the Department’s
calculations.
Similarly, restricting the basket of
countries to include only countries that
are economically comparable to each
NME is not feasible and would
undermine the consistency and
predictability of the Department’s
regression analysis. A basket of
‘‘economically comparable’’ countries
could be extremely small. For example,
there were five countries with GNI less
than US$1,000 in the Department’s 2005
calculation. A regression based on an
extremely small basket of countries
would be highly dependent on each and
every data point. The inclusion or
exclusion of any one country could have
an extreme effect on the regression
results. As described below, the
Department screens the available data
every year to ensure that they meet a
number of important data suitability
criteria. Therefore, the number and
composition of the countries in the
basket may vary unavoidably from year
to year. A larger basket minimizes this
potential for dramatic year–to-year
variability.
Relative basket size would not be
such a critical factor if there were a
perfect correlation between GNI and
wages. If this were the case, a precise
regression line could be derived from
suitable data from only two countries.
However, while there is a strong world–
wide relationship between wages and
GNI (the r–square for the Department’s
2005 calculation was .92, indicating an
extremely strong relationship between
GNI and wages), there is nevertheless
variability in the data. For example, in
the Department’s 2005 calculation,
observed wages did not increase in
lockstep with increases in GNI in the
five countries with GNI less than
US$1,000: Pakistan, with a GNI of
US$520, had reported a wage of
US$0.38 per hour while Sri Lanka, with
a GNI of US$930, had reported a wage
of US$0.34 per hour. As stated above, a
larger basket minimizes the effects of
any single data point and, thereby,
better captures the global relationship
between wages and GNI. More data is,
E:\FR\FM\19OCN1.SGM
19OCN1
cprice-sewell on PROD1PC66 with NOTICES
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 202 / Thursday, October 19, 2006 / Notices
therefore, better than less data for the
purposes of the Department’s regression
analysis, provided it is suitable and
reliable data.
For this reason, consistent with the
regulation and the statute, the
Department’s methodology relies on a
significantly larger basket of countries.
This maximizes the accuracy of the
regression results, minimizes the effects
of the potential year–to-year variability
in the basket, and provides
predictability and fairness. Importantly,
the Department notes that economic
comparability is established in the
regression calculation through the GNI
of the NME in question, which ensures
that the result represents a wage rate for
a country economically comparable to
the NME.
With regard to the use of an
alternative regression methodology, the
Department notes that in its Proposed
Rule, the Department explicitly stated
that it would utilize an OLS regression
analysis. See Proposed Rule, at 7345.
OLS regression analysis is a commonly
used analytical tool that is a basic
component of any statistical analysis
package. Like all statistical tools, the
OLS analysis has certain limitations and
cannot account for all characteristics of
any given dataset, including
heteroscedasticity. One of the
assumptions of the OLS regression
analysis is that the variance of the error
terms is constant across observations. If
the variance of the error terms is not
constant, the error terms are considered
heteroscedastic.
The data set upon which the
Department bases its regression analysis
changes on an annual basis. The
Department does not consider it
prudent, especially in light of its stated
intention to use an OLS analysis, to
decide on a year–by-year basis whether
or not the level of heteroscedasticity in
a given year’s data would weigh in favor
of using a GLS regression analysis.
Instead, the OLS regression analysis
allows the Department to rely on a
simple, easily–duplicated methodology
that enhances the fairness, predictability
and transparency of the Department’s
antidumping duty calculations, while
also ensuring their accuracy.
With regard to the CSUSTL comment
that the Department should rely on
‘‘labor cost’’ figures from Chapter 6 of
the ILO’s Yearbook of Labour Statistics,
the Department notes that the ILO
defines data under ‘‘Chapter 5b: Wages
in Manufacturing’’ as wages and
bonuses, i.e., pre–tax monetary
remuneration received by the employee.
This is the data set that the Department
relies upon in its calculations of
expected NME wage rates.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
14:50 Oct 18, 2006
Jkt 211001
The Department also notes that the
ILO defines ‘‘earnings’’ under Chapter 5
of its Yearbook of Labour Statistics as
being inclusive of ‘‘wages,’’ and as
including both bonuses and gratuities.
The Department agrees with CSUSTL
that, in order to ensure that its
calculation of expected NME wage rates
accurately reflects the remuneration
received by workers, it should rely on
‘‘earnings,’’ not ‘‘wages.’’
Chapter 6 data, on the other hand,
includes all costs to the producer
related to labor including wages,
benefits, housing, training, etc. As
described below, the Department is
already capturing as much of such labor
costs as possible in its financial ratio
calculations. The Department notes
further that significantly fewer countries
report Chapter 6 labor data than report
Chapter 5b labor data. As of August
2006, 15 market economy countries had
reported 2004 Chapter 6 data, while 65
market economy countries had reported
2004 Chapter 5b data. Chapter 6
therefore results in a significantly
smaller basket of countries for which
reliable data is available and may not
accurately capture the global average of
costs associated with labor.
The Department agrees with CSUSTL,
however, that in order to ensure that
labor costs not included in the ILO
defined ‘‘earnings’’ are accounted for in
its calculation of normal value, it is best
to adjust, where possible, the surrogate
financial ratios employed by the
Department to value overhead expenses,
selling, general and administrative
(‘‘SG&A’’) expenses, and profit.
Accordingly, it is the Department’s
practice to categorize all individually
identifiable labor costs not included in
the ILO’s definition of ‘‘earnings’’ under
Chapter 5 of the Yearbook of Labour
Statistics as overhead expenses. See
Folding Metal Tables and Chairs from
the People’s Republic of China: Final
Results of Antidumping Duty
Administrative Review, 71 FR 2905
(January 18, 2006) and accompanying
Issues and Decision Memorandum, at
comment 1. Such adjustments are fact–
specific in nature and subject to
available information on the record.
Specifically, where warranted,
individually identifiable labor costs in
the surrogate financial statements which
are not included in ‘‘earnings’’ are
categorized as overhead or SG&A
expenses for purposes of the
Department’s calculation of surrogate
financial ratios.
Finally, the Department agrees that
the basket of countries upon which the
regression is based should be expanded
to include all countries for which data
are available in order to ensure accuracy
PO 00000
Frm 00016
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
61721
and fairness. All such data must meet
the Department’s suitability
requirements described below, which
include contemporaneity and that the
data cover both men and women and all
reporting industries in the country.
Under its practice heretofore, the
Department includes data from Chapter
5 of the ILO Yearbook of Labour
Statistics that has been reported within
five years of the Base Year, thereby
considering a total of six years of data.
(As described below in Attachment 1,
the ‘‘Base Year’’ is the year upon which
the regression data are based and is two
years prior to the year in which the
Department conducts its regression
analysis.) In the course of reviewing its
methodology, the Department has
concluded that the inflation of data up
to five years potentially reduces the
accuracy of the calculation. Wage data
that are potentially six years old may
not represent the wage dynamics in
labor markets today. The Department
believes that, given the significant
availability of more contemporaneous
data, inflating old data is no longer
necessary in order to achieve an
acceptably large basket of countries. For
example, over 50 countries reported
suitable data within one year of 2003.
The Department expects that the
number of countries that meet the
Department’s suitability requirements
will increase over time, as a greater
number of countries report wage data to
ILO in a reliable manner.
Therefore, in its revised methodology,
the Department will only rely on ILO
wage data that have been reported
within one year prior to the Base Year,
thereby considering a total of two years
of data.
Revision of Methodology
Pursuant to the comments received
and the Department’s analysis thereof,
effective for the 2006 calculation of
expected NME wage rates, the
Department will make the following
revisions to its methodology:
1. The Department will only use
earnings data reported in Chapter
5b of the ILO statistics.
2. The basket of countries upon which
the wage regression is based will
include data from all market
economy countries that meet the
criteria described below and that
have been reported within 1 year
prior to the Base Year.
3. Each year, the Department’s annual
calculation of expected NME wage
rates will be subject to public notice
prior to the adoption of the
resulting expected NME wage rates
for use in antidumping proceedings.
Comment will be requested only
E:\FR\FM\19OCN1.SGM
19OCN1
61722
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 202 / Thursday, October 19, 2006 / Notices
with regard to potential clerical
errors in the Department’s
calculation in light of its stated
revised methodology.
Accordingly, the Department intends
to publish its 2006 expected NME wage
rates on its website in the autumn of
2006, together with a notice in the
Federal Register requesting comment
with regard to potential clerical errors in
light of the revised methodology
described below. The Department
intends to finalize its calculations
within one month thereafter.
The Department’s methodology is
described in full in below.
The Expected NME Wage Rate
Methodology
The Department’s regulations
generally describe the methodology by
which the Department calculates
expected NME wages:
cprice-sewell on PROD1PC66 with NOTICES
For labor, the Secretary will use
regression–based wage rates reflective of
the observed relationship between wages
and national income in market economy
countries. The Secretary will calculate
the wage rate to be applied in non–
market economy proceedings each year.
The calculation will be based on current
data, and will be made available to the
public.
19 CFR 351.408 (c)(3).
In accordance with Section
351.408(c)(3), the Department annually
calculates expected NME wages in two
steps. First, the Department uses an
ordinary least squares regression
analysis to estimate a linear relationship
between per–capita GNI and hourly
wages in market economy (‘‘ME’’)
countries. Second, the Department uses
the results of the regression and NME
GNI data to estimate hourly wage rates
for NME countries.
There is usually a two-year interval
between the current year and the most
recent reporting year of the data
required for this methodology due to the
practices of the respective data sources.
The Department bases its regression
analysis on this most recent reporting
year, which the Department refers to as
the ‘‘Base Year.’’ For example, the
Department relied upon data from 2001
to calculate expected NME wages in
2003, i.e., the ‘‘Base Year’’ for the 2003
calculation was 2001. In practice, the
‘‘Base Year,’’ i.e., the year upon which
the regression data are based, is two
years prior to the year in which the
Department conducts its regression
analysis.
1. Regression Analysis
The Department’s regression analysis,
which describes generally the
relationship between wages and GNI,
VerDate Aug<31>2005
14:50 Oct 18, 2006
Jkt 211001
relies upon four distinct data series: (A)
country–specific wage rate (earnings)
data from Chapter 5B of the
International Labor Organization’s
(‘‘ILO’’) Yearbook of Labour Statistics;
(B) country–specific consumer price
index (‘‘CPI’’) data from the
International Financial Statistics of the
International Monetary Fund (‘‘IMF’’);
(C) exchange rate data from the IMF’s
International Financial Statistics; and
(D) country–specific GNI data from the
World Development Indicators of the
World Bank (‘‘WB’’).
The wage rate data described above
are converted to hourly wage rates and
adjusted using CPI data to be
representative of the current Base Year.
The data are then converted to U.S.
dollars using the appropriate exchange
rate data. A regression analysis is
ultimately run on these adjusted wage
rate data and GNI. The following
sections describe each data series and
how it is used.
(A) Wage Data
For every country for which data is
available and suitable (as described
below), the Department chooses a single
wage rate that represents a broad
measure of wages for that country. The
Department will choose data that is
either contemporaneous with the Base
Year or one year prior. Thus, the
Department limits its selection of data to
a two year period.
The ILO Chapter 5B database
categorizes data under a number of
parameters.3 The Department prioritizes
these parameters in order to arrive at a
single wage rate for each country
representing the broadest possible
measure of wages. As such, there are
three criteria that all data must meet in
order to be considered suitable for the
Department’s regression analysis.
First, under the category ‘‘Type of
Data,’’ the Department will only use
data that is reported in ‘‘earnings.’’
Second, under the category ‘‘Sex,’’ the
Department will only use data that
cover both men and women.4
Third, under the category ‘‘Sub–
Classification,’’ the Department will
only use data that represent all reported
3 For example, ‘‘Type of Data,’’ i.e., whether the
data reported is ‘‘earnings’’ or ‘‘wages,’’’ ‘‘Sex,’’ i.e.,
male/female coverage; ‘‘Sub-Classification,’’ i.e. ,
coverage of different types of industry; ‘‘Worker
Coverage,’’ i.e. , coverage of different types of
workers, such as wage earners or salaried
employees; ‘‘Type of Data,’’ i.e., the unit of time for
which the wage is reported, such as per hour or per
month; and, ‘‘Source ID,’’ i.e., a code for the source
of the data; ‘‘Source,’’ i.e., the original survey source
of the data and ‘‘Classification,’’ i.e., the industrial
classification.
4 The Department does not consider values of
‘‘Indices, Men and Women’’ for this parameter.
PO 00000
Frm 00017
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
industries. This is indicated in the
database by a value of ‘‘Total’’ for the
‘‘Sub–Classification’’ parameter.
If there is more than one record in the
ILO database that meet these three
requirements, the Department will
choose the data point from the Base
Year over data from the prior year. At
times, there is more than one data
record in the ILO database that is both
(1) reported in the same, most
contemporaneous year and (2) meet the
three required criteria above. In such
cases, the Department chooses a single
data point by prioritizing the following
three parameters, described in greater
detail below: (1) ‘‘Worker Coverage,’’
i.e., coverage of different types of
workers; (2) ‘‘Type of Data,’’ i.e., the
unit of time for which the wage is
reported; and, (3) ‘‘Source ID,’’ i.e., a
code for the source of the data.
For example, for the parameter
‘‘Worker Coverage,’’ the Department
considers ‘‘wage earners’’ to be the best
measurement for calculating expected
NME wages and prioritizes such data
over ‘‘employees,’’ ‘‘salaried
employees’’ and ‘‘total employment,’’ in
that order.
When the values for all parameters
listed above are equal, the Department
prioritizes data reported on an hourly
basis over that reported on a daily,
weekly and monthly basis, in that order,
for the parameter ‘‘Type of Data.’’
Through this choice, the Department
minimizes potential error due to
converting daily, weekly or monthly
wages to hourly wages.
When the values for all parameters
listed above are equal, the Department
prioritizes data classified under the
International Standard Industrial
Classification (ISIC) Revision 3 (ISIC
Rev.3–D) over ISIC Revision 2 (ISIC Rev.
2–3). ISIC Rev. 3–D was revised in 1989
and is a more recent classification
standard than the 1968 ISIC Rev. 2–3.
See https://unstats.un.org/unsd/cr/
family2.asp?Cl=2 and https://
laborsta.ilo.org/applv8/data/isic2e.html.
Finally, when the values for all
parameters listed above are equal, the
Department prioritizes data with a
‘‘Source ID’’ value of ‘‘no value’’ over
‘‘1,’’ ‘‘2’’ and ‘‘3,’’ in that order.
The ILO data that are not reported on
an hourly basis are converted to an
hourly basis based on the premise that
there are 8 working hours per day, 5.5
working days a week and 24 working
days per month.
(B) CPI Data
Once hourly figures have been
calculated based on the wage rate data
discussed above, the wages are adjusted
to the Base Year on the basis of the
E:\FR\FM\19OCN1.SGM
19OCN1
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 202 / Thursday, October 19, 2006 / Notices
above to arrive at an estimated wage rate
for the NME. This is done for each NME.
(C) Exchange Rate Data
These inflation–adjusted wage data,
which are denominated in each
country’s national currency, are then
converted to U.S. dollars using Base
Year period–average exchange rates
reported by the IMF’s International
Financial Statistics.
Thus, using (A) wage data, (B) CPI
data and (C) exchange rate data,
discussed above, the Department arrives
at hourly wages, denominated in U.S.
dollars and adjusted for inflation for
each country for which all the above
data are available.
Finally, once the data have been
converted to U.S. dollars per hour and
adjusted for inflation, it is the
Department’s practice to eliminate
values that could not possibly be
reflective of actual wage levels or values
that vary in either direction in the
extreme from year to year (and which
probably reflect errors in the original
source data). For example, if a country
is found to have average wage levels of
US$0.01 per hour, the Department
would eliminate that value as
erroneous.
cprice-sewell on PROD1PC66 with NOTICES
Consumer Price Index for each country,
as reported by the IMF’s International
Financial Statistics. This adjustment is
made for any wage rate data not
reported for the Base Year.
With respect to the duty drawback
adjustment, the Department is directed
by section 772(c)(1)(B) of the Act, which
states that ‘‘{t}he price used to establish
export price and constructed export
price shall be -- (1) increased by … (B)
the amount of any import duties
imposed by the country of exportation
which have been rebated, or which have
not been collected, by reason of the
exportation of the subject merchandise
to the United States.’’
Based upon this statutory language,
the Department applies a two–prong test
to determine entitlement to a duty
drawback adjustment. That is, the party
claiming such adjustment must
establish that: (1) the import duty paid
and the rebate payment are directly
linked to, and dependent upon, one
another (or the exemption from import
duties is linked to exportation); and (2)
there were sufficient imports of the
imported raw material to account for the
drawback received upon the exports of
the manufactured product. See, e.g.,
Notice of Final Results of the Eleventh
Administrative Review of the
Antidumping Duty Order on Certain
Corrosion–Resistant Carbon Steel Flat
Products from the Republic of Korea, 71
FR 7513 (February 13, 2006) and
accompanying Issues and Decision
Memorandum, at comment 2 (‘‘CORE
from Korea’’). Moreover, the courts have
sustained the Department’s traditional
two–prong test. See, e.g., Wheatland
Tube Company v. United States, 414 F.
Supp. 2d 1271, 1287 (CIT 2006); Allied
Tube & Conduit Corp. v. United States,
374 F. Supp. 2d 1257, 1261 (CIT 2005);
Allied Tube & Conduit Corp. v. United
States, 132 F. Supp. 2d 1087, 1093 (CIT
2001); Far East Machinery Co., Ltd. v.
United States, 699 F. Supp. 309, 311
(CIT 1988); Carlisle Tire & Rubber Co. v.
United States, 657 F. Supp. 1287, 1289–
90 (CIT 1987).
The Department previously requested
and received comments regarding its
practice with respect to duty drawback
adjustments to export price in
antidumping proceedings. See Duty
Drawback Practice in Antidumping
Proceedings, 70 FR 37764 (June 30,
2005) and Duty Drawback Practice in
Antidumping Proceedings, 70 FR 44563
(August 3, 2005). Among other things,
the Department requested comments on
the appropriate methodology to apply
when duty drawback is claimed for
some, but not all, exports incorporating
the input in question. In past cases,
(D) GNI Data
The Department uses Base Year GNI
data for each of the countries in the
Department’s analysis, as reported by
the WB. GNI data are denominated in
U.S. dollars current for the Base Year.
The WB defines GNI per capita as
equivalent to gross national product
(‘‘GNP’’) per capita, which is ‘‘the dollar
value of a country’s final output of
goods and services in a year divided by
its population.’’
The Department conducts its linear,
ordinary least squares regression
analysis using the Base Year wages per
hour in U.S. dollars discussed above
and Base Year GNI per capita in U.S.
dollars to arrive at the following
equation: Wage[i] = Y–intercept + X–
coefficient * GNI. The X–coefficient
describes the slope of the line estimated
by the regression analysis, while the Y–
intercept is the point on the Y–axis
where the regression line intercepts the
Y–axis. The results of this regression
analysis describe generally the
relationship between hourly wages and
GNI.
2. Application of Regression Results to
NME GNI Data
The Department applies the NME
Base Year GNI to the equation presented
VerDate Aug<31>2005
14:50 Oct 18, 2006
Jkt 211001
Issue Three: Duty Drawback
Background
PO 00000
Frm 00018
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
61723
certain parties have argued that the
Department should allocate the total
amount of relevant drawback received
to total exports, regardless of
destination, to ensure that the
adjustment claimed on U.S. sales is not
overstated. See, e.g., CORE from Korea,
Issues and Decision Memorandum at
comment 2.
Some parties argued, for example, for
application of a ‘‘reasonableness’’
standard in this regard. They claim that,
while an adjustment in the full amount
of the duty drawback received should be
made when the foreign producer can
directly trace particular imported duty–
paid inputs through the subsequent
production process and into particular
finished goods that are exported to the
United States, this is an unlikely
situation. Because it is more likely that
exported goods may or may not actually
have incorporated the imported input, a
reasonable approach would involve
allocating the drawback received to all
exports that may have incorporated the
duty–paid input in question. By doing
so, these commenters claim, the
Department would reasonably avoid
excessive claims for drawback
adjustments in antidumping
calculations. These commenters further
suggest that parties claiming favorable
adjustments such as claims based upon
duty drawback carry the burden of proof
in this regard. See Statement of
Administrative Action, H. Doc. 103–
316, 103d Cong. 2d Sess., 829 (1994)
(‘‘{A}s with all adjustments which
benefit a responding firm, the
respondent must demonstrate the
appropriateness of such adjustment.’’).
The Department agrees with these
commenters and proposes to modify its
approach by limiting the duty drawback
adjustment in certain circumstances.
The Department generally agrees that it
should allocate the total amount of duty
drawback received across all exports
that may have incorporated the duty–
paid input in question, regardless of
destination, to ensure that the
adjustment claimed on U.S. sales is not
overstated. Absent such a limitation, the
Department is concerned that its current
practice of permitting an adjustment to
export price and constructed export
price for all duty drawback received,
whether or not it is related to U.S. sales,
is an inappropriate application of its
statutory authority to account for the
effects of foreign drawback programs on
price differentials between normal value
and U.S. price. Furthermore, the
Department is concerned that the
adjustment could be manipulated by
certain parties for purposes of obtaining
a more favorable dumping margin.
However, the Department will continue
E:\FR\FM\19OCN1.SGM
19OCN1
61724
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 202 / Thursday, October 19, 2006 / Notices
Dated: October 11, 2006.
David M. Spooner,
Assistant Secretary for Import
Administration.
[FR Doc. E6–17376 Filed 10–18–06; 8:45 am]
Comments (Duty Drawback Issue Only)
cprice-sewell on PROD1PC66 with NOTICES
to permit a full adjustment for duty
drawback received should the foreign
producer claiming such adjustment
demonstrate that it can directly trace the
particular imported duty–paid inputs
through the subsequent production
process and into particular finished
goods that are exported to the United
States. The Department welcomes
comment on this proposed
methodology.
DEADLINE FOR SUBMISSION OF
COMMENTS (on duty drawback):
November 17, 2006.
Environmental Literacy Grants for
Free-Choice Learning
Persons wishing to comment should
file a signed original and six copies of
each set of comments by the date
specified above. The Department will
consider all comments received before
the close of the comment period.
Comments received after the end of the
comment period will be considered, if
possible, but their consideration cannot
be assured. The Department will not
accept comments accompanied by a
request that a part or all of the material
be treated confidentially because of its
business proprietary nature or for any
other reason. The Department will
return such comments and materials to
the persons submitting the comments
and will not consider them in
development of any changes to its
methodology. All comments responding
to this notice will be a matter of public
record and will be available for public
inspection and copying at Import
Administration’s Central Records Unit,
Room B–099, between the hours of 8:30
a.m. and 5 p.m. on business days. The
Department requires that comments be
submitted in written form. The
Department recommends submission of
comments in electronic form to
accompany the required paper copies.
Comments filed in electronic form
should be submitted either by e–mail to
the webmaster below, or on CD–ROM,
as comments submitted on diskettes are
likely to be damaged by postal radiation
treatment.
Comments received in electronic form
will be made available to the public in
Portable Document Format (PDF) on the
Internet at the Import Administration
Web site at the following address:
https://ia.ita.doc.gov/.
Any questions concerning file
formatting, document conversion,
access on the Internet, or other
electronic filing issues should be
addressed to Andrew Lee Beller, Import
Administration Webmaster, at (202)
482–0866, e–mail address: webmaster–
support@ita.doc.gov.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
14:50 Oct 18, 2006
Jkt 211001
BILLING CODE 3510–DS–S
DEPARTMENT OF COMMERCE
National Oceanic and Atmospheric
Administration
[Docket No. 050317077–6264–03; I.D.
101306D]
Office of Education (OED),
Office of the Undersecretary of
Commerce for Oceans and Atmosphere
(USEC), National Oceanic and
Atmospheric Administration (NOAA),
Commerce.
ACTION: Notice of funding availability.
AGENCY:
SUMMARY: NOAA’s Office of Education
(OED) is requesting applications for
environmental literacy projects in
support of free-choice learning. The
proposed projects should support
NOAA’s vision which is: an informed
society that uses a comprehensive
understanding of the role of the ocean,
coasts, and atmosphere in the global
ecosystem to make the best social and
economic decisions. Successful projects
should reach significant segments of the
U.S. population at a State, multi-state or
national level. The environmental
literacy messages should clearly convey
how the Earth system influences a
project’s target audience, how the target
audience is influencing the Earth system
and how an environmentally literate
public can make informed decisions.
The goal of these projects should be to
provide adequate information to move
the audience’s knowledge beyond basic
awareness while reaching audiences
sufficient in size with a message that
promotes such a change. Funded
projects will last between one and five
years in duration and will create new,
or capitalize on existing, networks of
institutions, agencies and/or
organizations to provide common
messages about key concepts in Earth
System Science, for example the Ocean
Literacy Essential Principles and
Fundamental Concepts (https://
www.coexploration.org/oceanliteracy/
documents/
OceanLitConcepts_10.11.05.pdf).
Applications for exhibits involving
construction of part or all of a building
are not eligible for funding under this
announcement. Formal education
projects and projects whose main focus
PO 00000
Frm 00019
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
is on development of new data
visualizations and platforms will not be
considered for funding through this
announcement. Please visit https://
www.oesd.noaa.gov/funding_opps.html
for information on additional funding
opportunities in those areas. This
funding opportunity meets NOAA’s
Mission Goal to protect, restore and
manage the use of coastal and ocean
resources through ecosystems-based
management.
DATES: The deadline for preliminary
proposals is 5 p.m., e.s.t., November 29,
2006. The deadline for full applications
is 5 p.m., e.s.t. on March 21, 2007.
ADDRESSES: Pre-proposals may be
submitted through Grants.gov (https://
www.grants.gov), or if an applicant does
not have Internet access, three copies
must be mailed to Attn: ELG
Competition Manager, DOC/NOAA,
Office of Education, 1401 Constitution
Avenue, NW., Room 6863, Washington,
DC 20230. Please note that hard copies
submitted via the U.S. Postal Service
can take up to 4 weeks to reach this
office, therefore applicants are
recommended to send hard copies via
expedited shipping methods (e.g,
Airborne Express, DHL, Fed Ex, UPS).
Full applications may be submitted
through Grants.gov (https://
www.grants.gov), or if an applicant does
not have Internet access, one hard copy
should be sent to Attn: ELG Competition
Manager, DOC/NOAA Office of
Education, 1401 Constitution Avenue,
NW., Room 6863, Washington, DC
20230. If submitting a hard copy,
applicants are requested to provide a
CD–ROM of the application, including
scanned signed forms or forms with
electronic signatures. This
announcement will also be available at:
https://www.oesd.noaa.gov/
funding_opps.html or by contacting the
program official identified in FOR
FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
Sarah Schoedinger at
sarah.schoedinger@noaa.gov, telephone
704–370–3528 or Alyssa Gundersen at
Alyssa.Gundersen@noaa.gov, telephone
202–482–3739.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: NOAA’s
Office of Education (OED) is requesting
applications for environmental literacy
projects in support of free-choice
learning. The proposed projects should
support NOAA’s vision which is: an
informed society that uses a
comprehensive understanding of the
role of the ocean, coasts, and
atmosphere in the global ecosystem to
make the best social and economic
decisions. Successful projects should
reach significant segments of the U.S.
E:\FR\FM\19OCN1.SGM
19OCN1
Agencies
[Federal Register Volume 71, Number 202 (Thursday, October 19, 2006)]
[Notices]
[Pages 61716-61724]
From the Federal Register Online via the Government Printing Office [www.gpo.gov]
[FR Doc No: E6-17376]
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
DEPARTMENT OF COMMERCE
International Trade Administration
Antidumping Methodologies: Market Economy Inputs, Expected Non-
Market Economy Wages, Duty Drawback; and Request for Comments
AGENCY: Import Administration, International Trade Administration,
Department of Commerce.
ACTION: Announcement of Change in Methodology, Request for Comment
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
SUMMARY: This notice addresses three methodologies of the Department of
Commerce (``the Department'') in antidumping proceedings. First, the
Department is revising its approach concerning the use of market
economy inputs in the calculation of normal value in antidumping
proceedings involving non-market economy (``NME'') countries.
Specifically, the Department is revising its approach concerning cases
where an NME producer sources an input from both market economy
suppliers and from within the NME. Second, the Department is revising
its methodology for calculating expected NME wages in antidumping
proceedings involving NME countries. Third, the Department is
requesting comments on its approach concerning the calculation of duty
drawback adjustments to export price in antidumping proceedings when a
respondent producer obtains an input both from domestic and foreign
sources. On this latter issue, the Department is seeking comments on
the methodology that should be used when the producer receives duty
drawback on certain exports containing the input but not on other
exports containing the input.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: Lawrence Norton with regard to market
economy inputs, Shauna Lee-Alaia with regard to expected NME wages, and
John Kalitka with regard to duty drawback, Office of Policy, Import
Administration, U.S. Department of Commerce, 14\th\ Street and
Constitution Avenue, NW, Washington DC, 20230, 202-482-1579, 202-482-
2793, or 202-482-2730, respectively.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION:
Issue One: Market Economy Inputs
Background
In antidumping proceedings involving NME countries, the Department
calculates normal value by valuing the NME producer's factors of
production, to the extent possible, using prices from a market economy
that is at a comparable level of economic development and that is also
a significant producer of comparable merchandise. The goal of this
surrogate factor valuation is to use the ``best available information''
to determine normal value. See section 773(c)(1) of the Tariff Act of
1930, as amended (``the Act''); see also Shangdong Huraong General
Corp. v. United States, 159 F. Supp. 2d 714, 719 (CIT 2001). When an
NME producer purchases inputs from market economy suppliers and pays in
a market economy currency, the Department normally uses the average
actual price paid by the NME producer for these inputs to value the
input in question, where possible. See 19 CFR 351.408(c)(1); see also
Final Determination of Sales at Less Than Fair Value: Oscillating Fans
and Ceiling Fans from the People's Republic of China, 56 FR 55271,
55274-75 (October 25, 1991). When a portion of the input is purchased
from a market economy supplier and the remainder from a non-market
economy supplier, the Department will normally use the price paid for
the input sourced from market economy suppliers to value all of the
input,\1\ provided that the volume of the market economy input as a
share of total purchases from all sources is ``meaningful,'' a term
used in the Preamble to the Regulations but which is interpreted by the
Department on a case-by-case basis. See Antidumping Duties;
Countervailing Duties; Final Rule, 62 FR 27296, 27366 (May 19, 1997)
(``Final Rule''); see also Shakeproof v. United States, 268 F.3d 1376,
1382 (Fed. Cir. 2001) (``Shakeproof''). Such market economy input
purchases must also constitute arms-length, bona fide sales. See
Shakeproof, 268 F.3d at 1382-83.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1\ See 19 CFR 351.408(c)(1).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Additionally, the Department disregards market economy input
purchases when there is evidence that the prices for such inputs may be
distorted or when the facts of a particular case otherwise demonstrate
that market economy input purchase prices are not the best available
information. For example, the Department disregards all input values it
has reason to believe or suspect might be dumped or subsidized. See,
e.g., China National Machinery Import & Export Corporation v. United
States, 293 F. Supp. 2d 1334 (CIT 2003), as aff'd per curiam 04 Fed.
Appx. 183 (Federal Circuit, July 9, 2004). The Department has also
disregarded the prices of inputs that could not possibly have been used
in the production of subject merchandise during the period of
investigation or review. See, e.g., Final Determination of Sales at
Less Than Fair Value: Certain Frozen and Canned Warmwater Shrimp from
the Socialist Republic of Vietnam, 69 FR 71005, and accompanying Issues
and Decision Memorandum, at comment 8 (December 8, 2004) (``Shrimp'').
The Department has further rejected purchase prices from market
economies when the input in question was produced within an NME. See
Final Determination of Sales at Less Than Fair Value: Polyethylene
Retail Carrier Bags from the People's Republic of China, 69 FR 34125
and accompanying Issues and Decision Memorandum, at comment 4 (June 18,
2004).
The Department published on May 26, 2005, August 11, 2005, and
March 21, 2006, three notices in the Federal Register requesting
comment on its market economy inputs methodology in NME cases (70 FR
30418, 70 FR 46816,
[[Page 61717]]
and 71 FR 14176, respectively). In these notices, the Department
requested comment on various proposals concerning the Department's
approach in cases in which NME firms purchase a portion of a given
input from a market economy and source the remainder domestically. In
such instances, the Department must make a case-specific determination
as to what the best available information is for valuing the input: the
market-economy purchase price or another surrogate value. The guidance
given in the Department's regulations, as described above, is
``normally'' to use the prices paid for the market economy portion of
the input to value the entire input. While the regulations do not
elaborate as to what circumstances are ``normal,'' the Preamble states
that the Department will disregard market economy purchases if the
volume involved is not ``meaningful.'' In response to the Department's
March 21, 2006 request for comment, the Department received comments in
April 2006 from the following six interested parties: (1) the Committee
to Support U.S. Trade Laws (``CSUSTL''); (2) the United States Steel
Corporation (``U.S. Steel''); (3) the American Furniture Manufacturers
Committee (``Furniture Committee''); (4) Stewart and Stewart; (5) the
Ministry of Commerce of the People's Republic of China (``PRC
MOFCOM''); and (6) Trade Pacific.
The Department requested comment on its market economy inputs
practice for two reasons. First, the undefined nature of what
constitutes a ``meaningful'' quantity of market economy purchases
implies that the Department must currently make case-specific decisions
as to whether to accept market economy purchase prices to value inputs.
This creates unpredictability as to what values would ultimately be
used in the dumping calculation. Parties can advocate accepting or
disregarding the use of market economy purchase prices in individual
cases, but do not have a concrete framework for doing so. Indeed,
parties representing NME exporters have argued that market economy
purchase prices nearly always constitute the ``best available
information'' to use in the Department's dumping calculations, whereas
parties representing domestic industry have argued that market economy
purchases should almost never be used to value the portion of an input
that was sourced domestically within the NME. This conflicting
understanding as to when market economy purchases should be used to
value an entire input is also evident in the submissions the Department
received in response to its requests for comment on its market economy
inputs approach. Absent an announced threshold as to what quantities
are generally considered to be ``meaningful,'' parties would continue
to argue this issue without the benefit of any clear guidance from the
Department.
The Department's second reason for requesting comment on its market
economy inputs approach was its concern that it may, in some cases,
have used market economy input purchase prices to value an entire input
even when these prices may not have been the ``best available
information.'' While the Department has not had a specific threshold
for what constitutes a ``meaningful'' quantity, the Department is
concerned that accepting a market economy input value when the portion
sourced from a market economy is too low may not constitute the best
available information, particularly when no additional scrutiny is
applied to ensure that the market economy price is representative of
what the total price would have been had the firm purchased solely from
market economy suppliers. This is a potential problem because the
Department has greater confidence that the market economy purchase
price is reflective of total purchase values of the input (and, thus,
that it represents the ``best available information'') when the
proportion of the total volume of the input that is sourced from market
economies is higher. To take an extreme example, where an NME exporter
purchases all of a given input from a market economy supplier, the
Department can be confident that this price reflects total purchase
value of the input. Conversely, if an NME firm purchases a tiny
quantity of the input from market economy suppliers and sources the
rest domestically, the Department may have little or no confidence that
this purchase price reflects the NME firm's overall purchases of the
input. There might be numerous factors that could easily distort a
single, small volume market economy purchase price, for example: sample
sales, ``bundling'' of the purchase at a low price with other purchases
at higher prices, limited quantities available on the market at an
unusually low price, or brief plunges in the market price for the
input. Of course, even a single purchase of an input might also,
depending on the facts, be representative of what an NME exporter's
purchases would have been had it sourced all of the input in question
from the market economy source throughout the period of investigation
or review. As a general rule, however, the Department typically rejects
purchases of small quantities because ``insignificant'' quantities are
less likely to be representative of a company's cost of sourcing the
entire input. See Final Determination of Sales at Less Than Fair Value
and Negative Final Determination of Critical Circumstances: Certain
Color Television Receivers from the People's Republic of China, 69 FR
20594 and accompanying Issues and Decision Memorandum, at comment 12
(April 16, 2004).
This was the intended reasoning in the Preamble to the Regulations,
which states that the Department ``would not rely on the price paid by
an NME producer to a market economy supplier if the quantity of the
input purchased was insignificant. Because the amounts purchased from
the market economy supplier must be meaningful, this requirement goes
some way in addressing the commenter's concern that the NME producer
may not be able to fulfill all of its needs at that price.'' See Final
Rule, 62 at 27366. By announcing a basic threshold of what constitutes
such a ``meaningful'' quantity, and by making it high enough to reduce
the chance of using a distorted price, without setting it too high to
routinely prevent the use of market economy input prices, the
Department can give greater effect to the intent of the regulations and
improve its market economy inputs practice, to the benefit of all
parties. This was the reasoning behind some of the proposals the
Department put forward in its Federal Register notices soliciting
comment on its methodology in this area. This decision, along with a
discussion of the relevant public comments, is set forth below.
Statement of Policy
Drawing on the many submissions the Department has received in
response to its requests for comment, the Department is now revising
its methodology. While the Department may still consider amending its
regulations to remove the regulatory requirement that the Department
``normally'' use market economy input prices to value the entire amount
of such inputs, the Department is now establishing clearer guidance as
to the circumstances in which it will accept market economy purchase
prices to value an entire input. The Department is now instituting a
rebuttable presumption that market economy input prices are the best
available information for valuing an entire input when the total volume
of the input purchased
[[Page 61718]]
from all market economy sources during the period of investigation or
review exceeds 33 percent of the total volume of the input purchased
from all sources during the period. In these cases, unless case-
specific facts provide adequate grounds to rebut the Department's
presumption, the Department will use the weighted-average market
economy purchase price to value the entire input. Alternatively, when
the volume of an NME firm's purchases from market economy suppliers as
a percentage of its total volume of purchases during the period of
review is below 33 percent, but where these purchases are otherwise
valid and meet the Department's existing conditions (described in the
Background section above), the Department will weight-average the
weighted-average market economy purchase price with an appropriate
surrogate value according to their respective shares of the total
volume of purchases, unless case-specific facts provide adequate
grounds to rebut the presumption. In determining whether market economy
purchases meet this 33 percent threshold, the Department will compare
the volume that the producer purchased from market economy sources
during the period of investigation or review with the respondent's
total purchases during the period.\2\ When a firm has made market
economy input purchases that may have been dumped or subsidized, are
not bona fide, or are otherwise not acceptable for use in a dumping
calculation, the Department will exclude them from the numerator of the
ratio to ensure a fair determination of whether valid market economy
purchases meet the 33 percent threshold. This addresses the comment by
Trade Pacific that the Department explain how it intends to calculate
whether a given quantity of purchases meets the threshold, and ensures
a fair comparison between acceptable market economy purchases and total
purchases of the input during the period of investigation or review.
Morever, because this 33 percent threshold constitutes a rebutable
presumption, parties will have an opportunity to demonstrate that case-
specific facts outweigh the presumption.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\2\ Notwithstanding the determination the Department reached in
Shrimp, at comment 8, the Department will examine if and when the
inputs were used in the production process when case-specific
conditions demand it. Unless there are case-specific reasons to
examine other criteria, the Department will base its decision on
whether to accept market economy input purchases to value the entire
input on the relative share of market economy purchases during the
period of investigation or review to total purchases during the
period of investigation or review.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The practice described above is consistent with our current
regulations directing the Department to ``normally'' use market economy
input prices to value an entire input. While, as discussed above, the
term ``normally'' is not defined in the regulations, it has been
established in both the Preamble and through the Department's long-
standing case precedent that the Department may decline to accept
market economy purchases to value an input when the volume involved is
insignificant. See, e.g., Preliminary Results of Administrative Review:
Automotive Glass Windshields from China, 70 FR 24373, 24380 (May 9,
2005) (``Windshields'') (``{w{time} here the quantity of the input
purchased from market-economy suppliers was insignificant, the
Department will not rely on the price paid by an NME producer to a
market-economy supplier because it cannot have confidence that a
company could fulfill all its needs at that price.''). Windshields is
representative of the Department's consistent standard that it will
rely on market economy purchases to value an entire input only when the
share of the input sourced from market economy suppliers, relative to
the total volume purchased, is high enough that the Department has
confidence that the market economy purchase price is reflective of the
firm's total purchases of the input.
Accordingly, the Department's decision to introduce a flexible 33
percent threshold represents an extension of its previous practice.
This standard of 33 percent is consistent with a threshold that the
Department has defended, and the Court has upheld, as constituting a
``meaningful'' quantity in a prior case. See Shakeproof, 268 F.3d at
1382-83. However, the Department is now announcing what will generally
constitute a ``meaningful'' or ``significant'' quantity, as opposed to
making this determination on a strictly case-specific basis and without
general guidance. Establishing a proportional, rather than absolute,
threshold is also consistent with the logic described in Windshields,
because the decision of whether to accept market economy input
purchases to value an entire input rests on whether market economy
purchases are reflective of what the total price would have been had
the firm purchased solely from market economy suppliers.
Some commenters (including PRC MOFCOM) have argued that the
Department's proposed policy statements provide solutions to what are
only theoretical problems. These parties argue that even if
``bundling,'' price fluctuations or other factors that could distort
market economy purchases exist, they have not been shown to be a
problem in past cases and so there is no need for a remedy. The
Department disagrees with this assertion. The Department cannot be
privy to the circumstances governing every purchase of market economy
inputs, nor can it be expected to conduct an analysis of each input
market to see if given sales were representative of what the total
price would have been had the firm purchased solely from market economy
suppliers. Instead, the Department has always relied on the quantity of
the input sourced from market economies as a proxy to gauge its
relative confidence that the market economy purchase price is indeed
reflective of the total volume of the input. The only difference is
that the Department is now announcing a threshold, rather than making
exclusively case-specific decisions.
On this point, PRC MOFCOM and others have argued that the
Department should not establish a ``bright line'' threshold, that any
threshold is arbitrary, and that the Department already has sufficient
discretion to disregard market economy purchases that are not
legitimate or bona fide. As described above, however, the Department is
not introducing a rigid, ``bright line'' threshold, but rather a
threshold that is amenable to interpretation in the light of case-
specific facts and circumstances. Moreover, this threshold is not
arbitrary, but is carefully crafted to balance two competing concerns;
i.e. to ensure that market economy purchases are reflective of total
purchases without contravening the regulatory requirement to
``normally'' accept market economy purchase prices to value an entire
input when they are available.
In response to the Department's proposal to weight-average the
market economy purchase price with a surrogate value when the share of
market economy purchases falls below the Department's flexible
threshold, PRC MOFCOM argued that there can be only one single source
of the ``best available information,'' and if the market economy
purchase price constitutes the best information for valuing the portion
of the input sourced from market economy countries, it must also
constitute the best information for valuing the entire input. The
Department disagrees with this assertion, and considers that the ``best
available information'' in cases in which a respondent purchases a
given input both domestically and from market
[[Page 61719]]
economy sources may be, depending on the circumstances, a weighted-
average of a surrogate value and a market economy purchase price. The
fact that a given price is valid for a (relatively small) portion of
the input in question does not necessarily mean that it is
representative of the firm's total purchases of the input. While market
economy input purchase prices present a valid price for the market
economy purchases that an NME firm actually made, and the Department
will use these data, when possible, to value the portion of the input
purchased from market economy sources, these prices may not always be
the best available information for valuing the portion of the input
produced within the NME. When the Department cannot be confident that
this price is representative, however, if the price is otherwise valid
(as in being bona fide, not subsidized, etc.), weight-averaging an
appropriate surrogate value with the market economy purchase price
would be the most accurate valuation of the input.
Other parties (including U.S. Steel, Stewart and Stewart, and
CSUSTL) argue that except in rare cases, the Department should never
accept market economy input purchases to value the portion of the input
sourced domestically within the NME. Such a policy would contradict the
applicable regulation, which clearly directs the Department to
``normally'' use market economy input purchases to value the entire
input, even if the market economy purchases formed only a portion of an
NME firm's total purchases of the input. The Department may consider a
regulatory change in the future to grant it greater discretion in this
area. Nevertheless, the Department disagrees with the assertion that
market economy inputs never constitute the ``best available
information'' just as it disagrees that these purchases always do so.
Whether the best available information to value the NME-produced
portion of the input is the price of the firm's market economy input
purchases or another surrogate value is a decision that should guided
by the relative shares of the two types of purchases, as well as by
case-specific facts. U.S. Steel argues that ``establishing a bright
line threshold for market economy input purchases (i.e., more than 33
percent) would encourage respondents to manipulate the results so as to
favorably affect the calculation of their dumping margins.'' The
Department does not agree that a change in respondents' behavior as a
result of this policy, by itself, amounts to ``manipulation.''
Moreover, it is the Department's view that requiring parties, in most
cases, to meet a 33 percent threshold actually reduces the opportunity
for manipulation.
The Department's flexible percentage threshold of 33 percent for
accepting market economy purchase prices to value an entire input will
improve the predictability and accuracy of the Department's analysis,
while continuing to meet the Department's regulatory requirement to
``normally'' use market economy purchases to value inputs when they are
available. Predictability will be improved because parties will have a
clearer idea of when the Department will accept market economy purchase
prices to value an entire input. The Department will be able to
calculate more accurate dumping margins, because the threshold sets a
reasonable ratio of the market economy-sourced portion to that produced
in the NME so that the Department can be more confident in the
representativeness of the market economy purchase prices. However, this
threshold is also not set so high that it would contradict the
regulatory guidance on this issue. Finally, the fact that this
threshold represents a rebuttable presumption means that it will be
flexible, allowing the Department to take into account any case-
specific facts that may arise.
The approach detailed above will take effect for all segments of
NME proceedings that are initiated after publication of this notice in
the Federal Register.
Issue Two: Expected NME Wages
Background
With regard to its calculation of expected NME wages, the
Department stated in its November 17, 2004 final determination in the
antidumping duty investigation of sales at less than fair value
regarding Wooden Bedroom Furniture from the People's Republic of China,
that it would ``invite comments from the general public on this matter
in a proceeding separate from the (Furniture) investigation.'' Final
Determination of Sales at Less Than Fair Value: Wooden Bedroom
Furniture From the People's Republic of China, 69 FR 67313 and
accompanying Issues and Decision Memorandum, at comment 23 (November
17, 2004). On June 30, 2005, the Department published a detailed
description of its methodology for the calculation of expected NME
wages and a request for comment. See Expected Non-Market Economy Wages:
Request for Comment on Calculation Methodology, 70 FR 37761 (June 30,
2005) (``Wage Rate FR''). The Department received comments on August 1,
2005, from the following six interested parties: (1) CSUSTL; (2)
Grunfeld, Desiderio, Lebowitz, Silverman & Klestadt (``Grunfeld''); (3)
Lacquer Craft Manufacturing Company, Ltd.; (4) Dorbest Limited; (5) PRC
MOFCOM; and (6) the Ministry of Trade of the Socialist Republic of
Vietnam (``VN Ministry of Trade'').
The Department's expected NME wages are currently calculated each
year in two steps. First, the relationship between hourly wage rates
(obtained from the International Labor Organization's (``ILO'')
Yearbook of Labour Statistics, relying on data that has been reported
within the six-year period described below) and per-capita gross
national income (``GNI'') (obtained from the World Bank) from market-
economy countries (the ``basket of countries'') is estimated using an
ordinary least squares (``OLS'') regression analysis. Second, the GNI
of each of the countries designated by the Department as an NME is
applied to the regression, which yields an expected hourly wage rate
for each NME. For further information, see Wage Rate FR.
PRC MOFCOM and the other interested parties (excluding CSUSTL)
(``PRC MOFCOM et al.'') argued that when the Department is valuing any
factor of production, including labor, the Department is obliged to use
data from economically comparable countries and that the inclusion of
countries not considered economically comparable is in contravention of
our statute, citing 19 U.S.C. Sec. 1677b(c)(4) and Antidumping Duties;
Countervailing Duties, Part II, 62 FR 27296, 27367 (May 19, 1997)
(``Final Rule''). Finally, PRC MOFCOM et al. asserted that the
Department's original intention was to limit the regression analysis to
economically comparable countries, citing Antidumping Duties;
Countervailing Duties Part II, 61 FR 7308 (February 27, 1996)
(``Proposed Rule'').
Accordingly, these parties proposed that the Department revert to
its former practice of valuing direct labor using a surrogate wage rate
from a surrogate country selected in each individual proceeding, or an
average of the wage rates for the countries designated by the
Department as economically comparable to the NME at the outset of each
proceeding. Alternatively, some parties proposed that the Department
should estimate the relationship between wage rates and per-capita GNI
only for countries that are economically comparable to the NME country
in question, defined by either the Import Administration's Office of
Policy or by the World Bank's national income
[[Page 61720]]
classifications. These parties asserted that the inclusion of non-
comparable countries is both distortive and contrary to the
Department's statutory directive to use ``economically comparable''
surrogate values.
Alternatively, acknowledging that the Department has a stated
preference for more data when valuing labor, these parties proposed
that the Department expand its basket of countries to include all
countries for which the required data are available.
Finally, some parties argued that the Department should use a
generalized least squares (``GLS'') methodology for its regression
analysis in order to account for heteroscedasticity in the data set.
CSUSTL argued that the Department is required to value all factors
of production for a given respondent, and must therefore capture all
labor costs experienced by the respondent. Accordingly, CSUSTL proposed
that the Department change its practice to rely on ``labor cost''
figures from Chapter 6 of the ILO's Yearbook of Labour Statistics or,
failing that, that the Department should only use data from Chapter 5
that captures ``employee earnings'' rather than both earnings and
wages. CSUSTL also noted that in order to capture all factors of
production and other costs, the Department's calculation of surrogate
financial ratios must be adjusted according to the labor cost elements
that are included in the Department's expected NME wage rates.
Statement of Policy
Section 733(c) of the Act provides that the Department will value
the factors of production in an NME using the best available
information regarding the value of such factors in a market economy
country or countries considered to be appropriate by the administering
authority. The statute only requires that when valuing the factors of
production, the Department utilize, to the extent possible, the prices
or costs of factors of production in one or more market economy
countries that are at a level of comparable economic development. See
Section 733(c)(4) of the Act.
While surrogate values for other factors of production are selected
from a single surrogate country, the Department determined in its Final
Rule that it would be more accurate to base estimated labor values on
data from many countries, stating that ``more data is better than less
data, and that averaging of multiple data points (or regression
analysis) should lead to more accurate results in valuing any factor of
production. However, it is only for labor that we have a relatively
consistent and complete database covering many countries.'' See Final
Rule at 62 FR 27367.
Accordingly, section 351.408(c)(3) of the Department's regulations
provides that:
For labor, the Secretary will use regression-based rates reflective
of the observed relationship between wages and national income in
market economy countries. The Secretary will calculate the wage rate
to be applied in nonmarket economy proceedings each year. The
calculation will be based on current data, and will be made
available to the public.
19 CFR 351.408 (c)(3).
The Department's regulations concerning the valuation of labor were
promulgated as part of a public notice and comment process. In the
Proposed Rule the Department explained the benefits of a wage rate
derived from a regression analysis, which include fairness and
predictability. The Proposed Rule states:
Moreover, use of this average wage rate will contribute to both
the fairness and the predictability of NME proceedings. By avoiding
the variability in results depending on which economically
comparable country happens to be selected as the surrogate, the
results are much fairer to all parties. To enhance predictability,
the average wage to be applied in any NME proceeding will be
calculated by the Department each year, based on the most recently
available data, and will be available to any interested party.
See Proposed Rule, at 7345.
PRC MOFCOM et. al.'s comment that the Department should abandon its
regression-based calculation of expected NME wage rates in favor of the
use of a single surrogate value for wage rates would contravene the
Department's regulations, which direct the Department to use
regression-based labor rates. In addition, as the Department noted in
the Proposed Rule, while there is a strong positive correlation between
wage rates and GNI, there is also variation in the wage rates of
comparable market economies. For example, the Department's November
2005 regression illustrates that the observed hourly wage rates for
market economy countries with national incomes below US$1,000 ranged
from US$0.23 to US$0.94. See https://ia.ita.doc.gov/wages/03wages/
110805-2003-Tables/03wages-110805.html. Therefore, if the Department
adopted this suggestion in a proceeding involving an NME country with a
GNI under US$1,000, values for labor might range from US$0.23 to
US$0.94, depending on which economically comparable country is selected
as the surrogate. See Proposed Rule at 7345. The Department is able to
avoid this variability through the regression-based methodology for
estimating wage rates due to the availability of reliable wage rate
data and the consistent relationship over time between wage rates and
GNI. The Department relies upon what is, in essence, an average wage
rate, indexed to each NME's level of economic development via its GNI.
Under the Department's regression methodology, the value for labor will
be the same in every proceeding involving a given NME. This enhances
the fairness and predictability of the Department's calculations.
Similarly, restricting the basket of countries to include only
countries that are economically comparable to each NME is not feasible
and would undermine the consistency and predictability of the
Department's regression analysis. A basket of ``economically
comparable'' countries could be extremely small. For example, there
were five countries with GNI less than US$1,000 in the Department's
2005 calculation. A regression based on an extremely small basket of
countries would be highly dependent on each and every data point. The
inclusion or exclusion of any one country could have an extreme effect
on the regression results. As described below, the Department screens
the available data every year to ensure that they meet a number of
important data suitability criteria. Therefore, the number and
composition of the countries in the basket may vary unavoidably from
year to year. A larger basket minimizes this potential for dramatic
year-to-year variability.
Relative basket size would not be such a critical factor if there
were a perfect correlation between GNI and wages. If this were the
case, a precise regression line could be derived from suitable data
from only two countries. However, while there is a strong world-wide
relationship between wages and GNI (the r-square for the Department's
2005 calculation was .92, indicating an extremely strong relationship
between GNI and wages), there is nevertheless variability in the data.
For example, in the Department's 2005 calculation, observed wages did
not increase in lockstep with increases in GNI in the five countries
with GNI less than US$1,000: Pakistan, with a GNI of US$520, had
reported a wage of US$0.38 per hour while Sri Lanka, with a GNI of
US$930, had reported a wage of US$0.34 per hour. As stated above, a
larger basket minimizes the effects of any single data point and,
thereby, better captures the global relationship between wages and GNI.
More data is,
[[Page 61721]]
therefore, better than less data for the purposes of the Department's
regression analysis, provided it is suitable and reliable data.
For this reason, consistent with the regulation and the statute,
the Department's methodology relies on a significantly larger basket of
countries. This maximizes the accuracy of the regression results,
minimizes the effects of the potential year-to-year variability in the
basket, and provides predictability and fairness. Importantly, the
Department notes that economic comparability is established in the
regression calculation through the GNI of the NME in question, which
ensures that the result represents a wage rate for a country
economically comparable to the NME.
With regard to the use of an alternative regression methodology,
the Department notes that in its Proposed Rule, the Department
explicitly stated that it would utilize an OLS regression analysis. See
Proposed Rule, at 7345. OLS regression analysis is a commonly used
analytical tool that is a basic component of any statistical analysis
package. Like all statistical tools, the OLS analysis has certain
limitations and cannot account for all characteristics of any given
dataset, including heteroscedasticity. One of the assumptions of the
OLS regression analysis is that the variance of the error terms is
constant across observations. If the variance of the error terms is not
constant, the error terms are considered heteroscedastic.
The data set upon which the Department bases its regression
analysis changes on an annual basis. The Department does not consider
it prudent, especially in light of its stated intention to use an OLS
analysis, to decide on a year-by-year basis whether or not the level of
heteroscedasticity in a given year's data would weigh in favor of using
a GLS regression analysis. Instead, the OLS regression analysis allows
the Department to rely on a simple, easily-duplicated methodology that
enhances the fairness, predictability and transparency of the
Department's antidumping duty calculations, while also ensuring their
accuracy.
With regard to the CSUSTL comment that the Department should rely
on ``labor cost'' figures from Chapter 6 of the ILO's Yearbook of
Labour Statistics, the Department notes that the ILO defines data under
``Chapter 5b: Wages in Manufacturing'' as wages and bonuses, i.e., pre-
tax monetary remuneration received by the employee. This is the data
set that the Department relies upon in its calculations of expected NME
wage rates.
The Department also notes that the ILO defines ``earnings'' under
Chapter 5 of its Yearbook of Labour Statistics as being inclusive of
``wages,'' and as including both bonuses and gratuities. The Department
agrees with CSUSTL that, in order to ensure that its calculation of
expected NME wage rates accurately reflects the remuneration received
by workers, it should rely on ``earnings,'' not ``wages.''
Chapter 6 data, on the other hand, includes all costs to the
producer related to labor including wages, benefits, housing, training,
etc. As described below, the Department is already capturing as much of
such labor costs as possible in its financial ratio calculations. The
Department notes further that significantly fewer countries report
Chapter 6 labor data than report Chapter 5b labor data. As of August
2006, 15 market economy countries had reported 2004 Chapter 6 data,
while 65 market economy countries had reported 2004 Chapter 5b data.
Chapter 6 therefore results in a significantly smaller basket of
countries for which reliable data is available and may not accurately
capture the global average of costs associated with labor.
The Department agrees with CSUSTL, however, that in order to ensure
that labor costs not included in the ILO defined ``earnings'' are
accounted for in its calculation of normal value, it is best to adjust,
where possible, the surrogate financial ratios employed by the
Department to value overhead expenses, selling, general and
administrative (``SG&A'') expenses, and profit. Accordingly, it is the
Department's practice to categorize all individually identifiable labor
costs not included in the ILO's definition of ``earnings'' under
Chapter 5 of the Yearbook of Labour Statistics as overhead expenses.
See Folding Metal Tables and Chairs from the People's Republic of
China: Final Results of Antidumping Duty Administrative Review, 71 FR
2905 (January 18, 2006) and accompanying Issues and Decision
Memorandum, at comment 1. Such adjustments are fact-specific in nature
and subject to available information on the record. Specifically, where
warranted, individually identifiable labor costs in the surrogate
financial statements which are not included in ``earnings'' are
categorized as overhead or SG&A expenses for purposes of the
Department's calculation of surrogate financial ratios.
Finally, the Department agrees that the basket of countries upon
which the regression is based should be expanded to include all
countries for which data are available in order to ensure accuracy and
fairness. All such data must meet the Department's suitability
requirements described below, which include contemporaneity and that
the data cover both men and women and all reporting industries in the
country.
Under its practice heretofore, the Department includes data from
Chapter 5 of the ILO Yearbook of Labour Statistics that has been
reported within five years of the Base Year, thereby considering a
total of six years of data. (As described below in Attachment 1, the
``Base Year'' is the year upon which the regression data are based and
is two years prior to the year in which the Department conducts its
regression analysis.) In the course of reviewing its methodology, the
Department has concluded that the inflation of data up to five years
potentially reduces the accuracy of the calculation. Wage data that are
potentially six years old may not represent the wage dynamics in labor
markets today. The Department believes that, given the significant
availability of more contemporaneous data, inflating old data is no
longer necessary in order to achieve an acceptably large basket of
countries. For example, over 50 countries reported suitable data within
one year of 2003. The Department expects that the number of countries
that meet the Department's suitability requirements will increase over
time, as a greater number of countries report wage data to ILO in a
reliable manner.
Therefore, in its revised methodology, the Department will only
rely on ILO wage data that have been reported within one year prior to
the Base Year, thereby considering a total of two years of data.
Revision of Methodology
Pursuant to the comments received and the Department's analysis
thereof, effective for the 2006 calculation of expected NME wage rates,
the Department will make the following revisions to its methodology:
1. The Department will only use earnings data reported in Chapter
5b of the ILO statistics.
2. The basket of countries upon which the wage regression is based
will include data from all market economy countries that meet the
criteria described below and that have been reported within 1 year
prior to the Base Year.
3. Each year, the Department's annual calculation of expected NME
wage rates will be subject to public notice prior to the adoption of
the resulting expected NME wage rates for use in antidumping
proceedings. Comment will be requested only
[[Page 61722]]
with regard to potential clerical errors in the Department's
calculation in light of its stated revised methodology.
Accordingly, the Department intends to publish its 2006 expected
NME wage rates on its website in the autumn of 2006, together with a
notice in the Federal Register requesting comment with regard to
potential clerical errors in light of the revised methodology described
below. The Department intends to finalize its calculations within one
month thereafter.
The Department's methodology is described in full in below.
The Expected NME Wage Rate Methodology
The Department's regulations generally describe the methodology by
which the Department calculates expected NME wages:
For labor, the Secretary will use regression-based wage rates
reflective of the observed relationship between wages and national
income in market economy countries. The Secretary will calculate the
wage rate to be applied in non-market economy proceedings each year.
The calculation will be based on current data, and will be made
available to the public.
19 CFR 351.408 (c)(3).
In accordance with Section 351.408(c)(3), the Department annually
calculates expected NME wages in two steps. First, the Department uses
an ordinary least squares regression analysis to estimate a linear
relationship between per-capita GNI and hourly wages in market economy
(``ME'') countries. Second, the Department uses the results of the
regression and NME GNI data to estimate hourly wage rates for NME
countries.
There is usually a two-year interval between the current year and
the most recent reporting year of the data required for this
methodology due to the practices of the respective data sources. The
Department bases its regression analysis on this most recent reporting
year, which the Department refers to as the ``Base Year.'' For example,
the Department relied upon data from 2001 to calculate expected NME
wages in 2003, i.e., the ``Base Year'' for the 2003 calculation was
2001. In practice, the ``Base Year,'' i.e., the year upon which the
regression data are based, is two years prior to the year in which the
Department conducts its regression analysis.
1. Regression Analysis
The Department's regression analysis, which describes generally the
relationship between wages and GNI, relies upon four distinct data
series: (A) country-specific wage rate (earnings) data from Chapter 5B
of the International Labor Organization's (``ILO'') Yearbook of Labour
Statistics; (B) country-specific consumer price index (``CPI'') data
from the International Financial Statistics of the International
Monetary Fund (``IMF''); (C) exchange rate data from the IMF's
International Financial Statistics; and (D) country-specific GNI data
from the World Development Indicators of the World Bank (``WB'').
The wage rate data described above are converted to hourly wage
rates and adjusted using CPI data to be representative of the current
Base Year. The data are then converted to U.S. dollars using the
appropriate exchange rate data. A regression analysis is ultimately run
on these adjusted wage rate data and GNI. The following sections
describe each data series and how it is used.
(A) Wage Data
For every country for which data is available and suitable (as
described below), the Department chooses a single wage rate that
represents a broad measure of wages for that country. The Department
will choose data that is either contemporaneous with the Base Year or
one year prior. Thus, the Department limits its selection of data to a
two year period.
The ILO Chapter 5B database categorizes data under a number of
parameters.\3\ The Department prioritizes these parameters in order to
arrive at a single wage rate for each country representing the broadest
possible measure of wages. As such, there are three criteria that all
data must meet in order to be considered suitable for the Department's
regression analysis.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\3\ For example, ``Type of Data,'' i.e., whether the data
reported is ``earnings'' or ``wages,''' ``Sex,'' i.e., male/female
coverage; ``Sub-Classification,'' i.e. , coverage of different types
of industry; ``Worker Coverage,'' i.e. , coverage of different types
of workers, such as wage earners or salaried employees; ``Type of
Data,'' i.e., the unit of time for which the wage is reported, such
as per hour or per month; and, ``Source ID,'' i.e., a code for the
source of the data; ``Source,'' i.e., the original survey source of
the data and ``Classification,'' i.e., the industrial
classification.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
First, under the category ``Type of Data,'' the Department will
only use data that is reported in ``earnings.''
Second, under the category ``Sex,'' the Department will only use
data that cover both men and women.\4\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\4\ The Department does not consider values of ``Indices, Men
and Women'' for this parameter.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Third, under the category ``Sub-Classification,'' the Department
will only use data that represent all reported industries. This is
indicated in the database by a value of ``Total'' for the ``Sub-
Classification'' parameter.
If there is more than one record in the ILO database that meet
these three requirements, the Department will choose the data point
from the Base Year over data from the prior year. At times, there is
more than one data record in the ILO database that is both (1) reported
in the same, most contemporaneous year and (2) meet the three required
criteria above. In such cases, the Department chooses a single data
point by prioritizing the following three parameters, described in
greater detail below: (1) ``Worker Coverage,'' i.e., coverage of
different types of workers; (2) ``Type of Data,'' i.e., the unit of
time for which the wage is reported; and, (3) ``Source ID,'' i.e., a
code for the source of the data.
For example, for the parameter ``Worker Coverage,'' the Department
considers ``wage earners'' to be the best measurement for calculating
expected NME wages and prioritizes such data over ``employees,''
``salaried employees'' and ``total employment,'' in that order.
When the values for all parameters listed above are equal, the
Department prioritizes data reported on an hourly basis over that
reported on a daily, weekly and monthly basis, in that order, for the
parameter ``Type of Data.'' Through this choice, the Department
minimizes potential error due to converting daily, weekly or monthly
wages to hourly wages.
When the values for all parameters listed above are equal, the
Department prioritizes data classified under the International Standard
Industrial Classification (ISIC) Revision 3 (ISIC Rev.3-D) over ISIC
Revision 2 (ISIC Rev. 2-3). ISIC Rev. 3-D was revised in 1989 and is a
more recent classification standard than the 1968 ISIC Rev. 2-3. See
https://unstats.un.org/unsd/cr/family2.asp?Cl=2 and https://
laborsta.ilo.org/applv8/data/isic2e.html.
Finally, when the values for all parameters listed above are equal,
the Department prioritizes data with a ``Source ID'' value of ``no
value'' over ``1,'' ``2'' and ``3,'' in that order.
The ILO data that are not reported on an hourly basis are converted
to an hourly basis based on the premise that there are 8 working hours
per day, 5.5 working days a week and 24 working days per month.
(B) CPI Data
Once hourly figures have been calculated based on the wage rate
data discussed above, the wages are adjusted to the Base Year on the
basis of the
[[Page 61723]]
Consumer Price Index for each country, as reported by the IMF's
International Financial Statistics. This adjustment is made for any
wage rate data not reported for the Base Year.
(C) Exchange Rate Data
These inflation-adjusted wage data, which are denominated in each
country's national currency, are then converted to U.S. dollars using
Base Year period-average exchange rates reported by the IMF's
International Financial Statistics.
Thus, using (A) wage data, (B) CPI data and (C) exchange rate data,
discussed above, the Department arrives at hourly wages, denominated in
U.S. dollars and adjusted for inflation for each country for which all
the above data are available.
Finally, once the data have been converted to U.S. dollars per hour
and adjusted for inflation, it is the Department's practice to
eliminate values that could not possibly be reflective of actual wage
levels or values that vary in either direction in the extreme from year
to year (and which probably reflect errors in the original source
data). For example, if a country is found to have average wage levels
of US$0.01 per hour, the Department would eliminate that value as
erroneous.
(D) GNI Data
The Department uses Base Year GNI data for each of the countries in
the Department's analysis, as reported by the WB. GNI data are
denominated in U.S. dollars current for the Base Year. The WB defines
GNI per capita as equivalent to gross national product (``GNP'') per
capita, which is ``the dollar value of a country's final output of
goods and services in a year divided by its population.''
The Department conducts its linear, ordinary least squares
regression analysis using the Base Year wages per hour in U.S. dollars
discussed above and Base Year GNI per capita in U.S. dollars to arrive
at the following equation: Wage[lsqb]i[rsqb] = Y-intercept + X-
coefficient [ast] GNI. The X-coefficient describes the slope of the
line estimated by the regression analysis, while the Y-intercept is the
point on the Y-axis where the regression line intercepts the Y-axis.
The results of this regression analysis describe generally the
relationship between hourly wages and GNI.
2. Application of Regression Results to NME GNI Data
The Department applies the NME Base Year GNI to the equation
presented above to arrive at an estimated wage rate for the NME. This
is done for each NME.
Issue Three: Duty Drawback
Background
With respect to the duty drawback adjustment, the Department is
directed by section 772(c)(1)(B) of the Act, which states that
``{t{time} he price used to establish export price and constructed
export price shall be -- (1) increased by [hellip] (B) the amount of
any import duties imposed by the country of exportation which have been
rebated, or which have not been collected, by reason of the exportation
of the subject merchandise to the United States.''
Based upon this statutory language, the Department applies a two-
prong test to determine entitlement to a duty drawback adjustment. That
is, the party claiming such adjustment must establish that: (1) the
import duty paid and the rebate payment are directly linked to, and
dependent upon, one another (or the exemption from import duties is
linked to exportation); and (2) there were sufficient imports of the
imported raw material to account for the drawback received upon the
exports of the manufactured product. See, e.g., Notice of Final Results
of the Eleventh Administrative Review of the Antidumping Duty Order on
Certain Corrosion-Resistant Carbon Steel Flat Products from the
Republic of Korea, 71 FR 7513 (February 13, 2006) and accompanying
Issues and Decision Memorandum, at comment 2 (``CORE from Korea'').
Moreover, the courts have sustained the Department's traditional two-
prong test. See, e.g., Wheatland Tube Company v. United States, 414 F.
Supp. 2d 1271, 1287 (CIT 2006); Allied Tube & Conduit Corp. v. United
States, 374 F. Supp. 2d 1257, 1261 (CIT 2005); Allied Tube & Conduit
Corp. v. United States, 132 F. Supp. 2d 1087, 1093 (CIT 2001); Far East
Machinery Co., Ltd. v. United States, 699 F. Supp. 309, 311 (CIT 1988);
Carlisle Tire & Rubber Co. v. United States, 657 F. Supp. 1287, 1289-90
(CIT 1987).
The Department previously requested and received comments regarding
its practice with respect to duty drawback adjustments to export price
in antidumping proceedings. See Duty Drawback Practice in Antidumping
Proceedings, 70 FR 37764 (June 30, 2005) and Duty Drawback Practice in
Antidumping Proceedings, 70 FR 44563 (August 3, 2005). Among other
things, the Department requested comments on the appropriate
methodology to apply when duty drawback is claimed for some, but not
all, exports incorporating the input in question. In past cases,
certain parties have argued that the Department should allocate the
total amount of relevant drawback received to total exports, regardless
of destination, to ensure that the adjustment claimed on U.S. sales is
not overstated. See, e.g., CORE from Korea, Issues and Decision
Memorandum at comment 2.
Some parties argued, for example, for application of a
``reasonableness'' standard in this regard. They claim that, while an
adjustment in the full amount of the duty drawback received should be
made when the foreign producer can directly trace particular imported
duty-paid inputs through the subsequent production process and into
particular finished goods that are exported to the United States, this
is an unlikely situation. Because it is more likely that exported goods
may or may not actually have incorporated the imported input, a
reasonable approach would involve allocating the drawback received to
all exports that may have incorporated the duty-paid input in question.
By doing so, these commenters claim, the Department would reasonably
avoid excessive claims for drawback adjustments in antidumping
calculations. These commenters further suggest that parties claiming
favorable adjustments such as claims based upon duty drawback carry the
burden of proof in this regard. See Statement of Administrative Action,
H. Doc. 103-316, 103d Cong. 2d Sess., 829 (1994) (``{A{time} s with all
adjustments which benefit a responding firm, the respondent must
demonstrate the appropriateness of such adjustment.'').
The Department agrees with these commenters and proposes to modify
its approach by limiting the duty drawback adjustment in certain
circumstances. The Department generally agrees that it should allocate
the total amount of duty drawback received across all exports that may
have incorporated the duty-paid input in question, regardless of
destination, to ensure that the adjustment claimed on U.S. sales is not
overstated. Absent such a limitation, the Department is concerned that
its current practice of permitting an adjustment to export price and
constructed export price for all duty drawback received, whether or not
it is related to U.S. sales, is an inappropriate application of its
statutory authority to account for the effects of foreign drawback
programs on price differentials between normal value and U.S. price.
Furthermore, the Department is concerned that the adjustment could be
manipulated by certain parties for purposes of obtaining a more
favorable dumping margin. However, the Department will continue
[[Page 61724]]
to permit a full adjustment for duty drawback received should the
foreign producer claiming such adjustment demonstrate that it can
directly trace the particular imported duty-paid inputs through the
subsequent production process and into particular finished goods that
are exported to the United States. The Department welcomes comment on
this proposed methodology.
DEADLINE FOR SUBMISSION OF COMMENTS (on duty drawback): November 17,
2006.
Comments (Duty Drawback Issue Only)
Persons wishing to comment should file a signed original and six
copies of each set of comments by the date specified above. The
Department will consider all comments received before the close of the
comment period. Comments received after the end of the comment period
will be considered, if possible, but their consideration cannot be
assured. The Department will not accept comments accompanied by a
request that a part or all of the material be treated confidentially
because of its business proprietary nature or for any other reason. The
Department will return such comments and materials to the persons
submitting the comments and will not consider them in development of
any changes to its methodology. All comments responding to this notice
will be a matter of public record and will be available for public
inspection and copying at Import Administration's Central Records Unit,
Room B-099, between the hours of 8:30 a.m. and 5 p.m. on business days.
The Department requires that comments be submitted in written form. The
Department recommends submission of comments in electronic form to
accompany the required paper copies. Comments filed in electronic form
should be submitted either by e-mail to the webmaster below, or on CD-
ROM, as comments submitted on diskettes are likely to be damaged by
postal radiation treatment.
Comments received in electronic form will be made available to the
public in Portable Document Format (PDF) on the Internet at the Import
Administration Web site at the following address: https://
ia.ita.doc.gov/.
Any questions concerning file formatting, document conversion,
access on the Internet, or other electronic filing issues should be
addressed to Andrew Lee Beller, Import Administration Webmaster, at
(202) 482-0866, e-mail address: webmaster-support@ita.doc.gov.
Dated: October 11, 2006.
David M. Spooner,
Assistant Secretary for Import Administration.
[FR Doc. E6-17376 Filed 10-18-06; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 3510-DS-S