Inclusive Competition and Market Integrity Under the Packers and Stockyards Act, 60010-60055 [2022-21114]
Download as PDF
60010
Federal Register / Vol. 87, No. 190 / Monday, October 3, 2022 / Proposed Rules
comment anonymously may do so by
entering ‘‘N/A’’ in the fields that would
identify the commenter.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: S.
Brett Offutt, Chief Legal Officer/Policy
Advisor, Packers and Stockyards
Division, USDA AMS Fair Trade
Practices Program, 1400 Independence
Ave. SW, Washington, DC 20250;
Phone: (202) 690–4355; or email:
s.brett.offutt@usda.gov.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION:
DEPARTMENT OF AGRICULTURE
Agricultural Marketing Service
9 CFR Part 201
[Doc. No. AMS–FTPP–21–0045]
RIN 0581–AE05
Inclusive Competition and Market
Integrity Under the Packers and
Stockyards Act
Agricultural Marketing Service,
Department of Agriculture (USDA).
ACTION: Proposed rule.
AGENCY:
The U.S. Department of
Agriculture’s (USDA) Agricultural
Marketing Service (AMS) is soliciting
comments on proposed revisions to the
regulations under the Packers and
Stockyards Act, 1921. The proposal
would prohibit certain prejudices
against market-vulnerable individuals
that tend to exclude or disadvantage
covered producers in those markets. The
proposal would identify retaliatory
practices that interfere with lawful
communications, assertion of rights, and
associational participation, among other
protected activities, as unjust
discrimination prohibited by the law.
The proposal would also identify
unlawfully deceptive practices that
violate the Packers and Stockyards Act
with respect to contract formation,
contract performance, contract
termination, and contract refusal. The
purpose of the rule is to promote
inclusive competition and market
integrity in the livestock, meats, poultry,
and live poultry markets.
DATES: Comments must be received by
December 2, 2022.
ADDRESSES: Comments must be
submitted through the Federal erulemaking portal at https://
www.regulations.gov and should
reference the document number and the
date and page number of this issue of
the Federal Register. AMS strongly
prefers comments be submitted
electronically. However, written
comments may be submitted (i.e.,
postmarked) via mail to S. Brett Offutt,
Chief Legal Officer, Packers and
Stockyards Division, USDA, AMS,
FTPP; Room 2097–S, Mail Stop 3601,
1400 Independence Ave. SW,
Washington, DC 20250–3601. All
comments submitted in response to this
proposed rule will be included in the
record and will be made available to the
public. Please be advised that the
identity of individuals or entities
submitting comments will be made
public on the internet at the address
provided above. Parties who wish to
lotter on DSK11XQN23PROD with PROPOSALS3
SUMMARY:
VerDate Sep<11>2014
20:25 Sep 30, 2022
Jkt 259001
Outline of the Notice of Proposed
Rulemaking
I. Introduction (Statutory Authority)
A. Background to This Rulemaking
B. Previous Rulemakings
II. Undue Prejudices or Disadvantages and
Discriminatory Practices
A. Agency Interpretation of Undue or
Unreasonable Prejudice or Disadvantage
and Unjust Discriminatory Practices
B. Prohibited Undue Prejudices or
Disadvantages and Unjust
Discrimination—Proposed
§ 201.304(a)(1)—Generally
i. Authority Provided by the Act
ii. Economic Rationale
iii. Specific Proposed Protected Bases
C. Cooperatives—Proposed § 201.304(a)(2)
D. Enumerated Undue Prejudices
E. Retaliation
i. Retaliation as Discrimination Under the
Act
ii. Economic Rationale
F. Prohibition on Retaliation—Proposed
§ 201.304(b)
G. Bases of Protected Activities—Proposed
§ 201.304(b).
i. Assertion of Rights
ii. Associational Participation
iii. Lawful Communications
H. Delineation of Protected Activities
I. Recordkeeping—Proposed § 201.304(c)
J. Request for Comments
III. Deceptive Practices
A. Scope of Deceptive Practices Regulated
B. Deceptive Practices in the Formation of
Contract
C. Deceptive Practices in the Operation of
Contract
D. Deceptive Practices in the Termination
of Contract
E. Deceptive Practices in Refusal To Deal
F. Request for Comments
IV. Severability
V. Required Regulatory Analyses
VI. Request for Comments
I. Introduction and Regulatory
Background
The rise of vertically integrated
contract agriculture and highly
concentrated local markets in livestock
and poultry over the last four decades
have increasingly left many producers
and growers (hereinafter producers,
unless otherwise noted) vulnerable to a
range of practices that unjustly exclude
them from and undermine their
economic opportunities in the
marketplace. The regulatory toolkit
PO 00000
Frm 00002
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
embodied in the Packers & Stockyards
Act, as amended (P&S Act or Act) (7
U.S.C. 181 et seq.), has not been
deployed to keep pace with these issues.
AMS is proposing this regulation to
enhance those basic protections that
modern livestock and poultry producers
need to promote inclusive competition
and market integrity. We invite
comment on a range of questions in this
proposal.
Specifically, AMS is proposing to:
• Prohibit, as undue prejudices,
disadvantages, and adverse actions
against ‘‘market vulnerable individuals’’
who are at heightened risk in relevant
markets;
• Prohibit, as unjust discrimination,
retaliatory and adverse actions that
interfere with lawful communications,
assertion of rights, associational
participation, and other protected
activities;
• Prohibit, as deceptive practices,
regulated entities employing pretexts,
false or misleading statements, or
omissions of material facts, in contract
formation, contract performance,
contract termination, and contract
refusal; and
• Require recordkeeping to support
USDA monitoring, evaluation, and
enforcement of compliance with aspects
of this rule.
AMS is proposing these modernized
regulations under the Act’s provisions
prohibiting undue prejudice, unjust
discrimination, and deception to
provide for clearer, more effective
standards to govern the modern
marketplace and to better protect,
through compliance and enforcement,
individually harmed producers and
growers. Enacted in 1921 ‘‘to
comprehensively regulate packers,
stockyards, marketing agents and
dealers,’’ 1 the P&S Act, among other
things, prohibits actions that hinder
integrity and competition in the
livestock and poultry markets. Section
202(a) of the Act states that it is
unlawful for any packer, swine
contractor, or live poultry dealer to
engage in or use any unfair, unjustly
discriminatory, or deceptive practice or
device.2 Section 202(b) of the Act states
that it is unlawful for any packer, swine
contractor, or live poultry dealer to
make or give any undue or unreasonable
preference or advantage to any
particular person or locality, or subject
any particular person or locality to any
undue or unreasonable prejudice or
disadvantage in any respect. The
Secretary of Agriculture (Secretary) has
1 Hays Livestock Comm’n Co. v. Maly Livestock
Comm’n Co., 498 F.2d 925, 927 (10th Cir. 1974).
2 7 U.S.C. 192(a).
E:\FR\FM\03OCP3.SGM
03OCP3
Federal Register / Vol. 87, No. 190 / Monday, October 3, 2022 / Proposed Rules
delegated the responsibility for
administering the P&S Act to AMS.
Within AMS, the Packers, and
Stockyards Division (PSD) of the FairTrade Practices Program has
responsibility for the day-to-day
administration of the P&S Act. The
current regulations implementing the
P&S Act are found in title 9, part 201 of
the Code of Federal Regulations (CFR).
Section 407 of the P&S Act (7 U.S.C.
228) provides that the Secretary ‘‘may
make such rules, regulations, and orders
as may be necessary to carry out the
provisions of this Act.’’ This proposed
rule, if finalized, would amend 9 CFR
part 201.
A. Background to This Rulemaking
lotter on DSK11XQN23PROD with PROPOSALS3
Congress enacted the P&S Act after
many years of concern about farmers
and ranchers being cheated and
mistreated. At the time, Congress
worried that the five very large
meatpackers’ control over the nation’s
food supply tended toward
monopolization, which could put
economic opportunity for producers and
their communities at risk, destroying
individual economic opportunity for
producers and smaller food businesses
and harming rural communities, among
other harms.3 Moreover, Congress
believed that existing antitrust and
market regulatory laws, including the
Sherman Act and Federal Trade
Commission Act, did not sufficiently
protect farmers and ranchers.4
Accordingly, in the P&S Act, Congress
gave the Secretary of Agriculture broad
authority to regulate the meatpacking
industry. The House of Representatives’
report on the P&S Act stated that it was
the ‘‘most comprehensive measure and
extends farther than any previous law in
the regulation of private business, in
time of peace, except possibly the
interstate commerce act.’’ 5 The
Conference Report on the P&S Act
stated that: ‘‘Congress intends to
exercise, in the bill, the fullest control
of the packers and stockyards which the
Constitution permits . . .’’ 6
In the early 1900s, meat packing in
the United States was highly
concentrated, with approximately 50 to
70 percent of the beef packing industry
controlled by the industry’s ‘‘Big Five:’’
Armour, Cudahy, Morris, Swift, and
3 See 61 Cong. Rec. 1860 (1921) (House Floor
Debate).
4 See, Shively, J. and Roberts, J., ‘‘Competition
Under the Packers and Stockyards Act: What
Now?’’ 15 Drake Journal of Agricultural Law 419,
422–423 (2010); and Current Legislation, 22
Columbia Law Review 68, 69 (1922).
5 House Report No. 67–77, at 2 (1921).
6 House Report No. 67–324, at 3 (1921).
VerDate Sep<11>2014
20:25 Sep 30, 2022
Jkt 259001
Wilson.7 A 1918 Federal Trade
Commission (FTC) meat industry
investigation found that in 1916 the Big
Five controlled the slaughter and
processing of 82 percent of cattle, 79
percent of calves, 87 percent of sheep,
and 63 percent of swine in the U.S.8
Those five dominant operators also
controlled an interlocking network of
the feed mills, stockyards, and
transportation infrastructure that
supported the industry. As extensively
documented in a report by the FTC,
which set the stage for Congressional
passage of the P&S Act, those five
packers deployed from their positions in
that market structure a range of
practices to further entrench their
dominance.9
At that same time, the Department of
Justice (DOJ) brought enforcement cases
under the Sherman Act against the
packing industry, which resulted in a
series of consent decrees (judicially
overseen agreements) that restructured
the market.10 The consent decrees,
together with the adoption of the P&S
Act, reformed market practices by
eliminating packer ownership of cattle
and their means of transporting it, and
reinforced market structures that—for a
period of time in the 20th century—
secured open, fair marketplaces for all,
such as terminal auction yards regulated
as stockyards by the Packers and
Stockyards Administration of USDA.11
By 1963, the four-firm concentration
ratio (the standard economic tool used
to evaluate the degree of concentration
in markets) had fallen to 26 percent in
beef and 33 percent in hogs.
Amidst slowing demand in the beef
and hog sectors, the dramatic growth of
demand in the poultry industry,
technological advances and increased
returns to scale in meat processing, and
a decline in Federal antitrust and fair
markets enforcement, concentration
returned to the meat packing industry.12
Between 1980 and 2020, the four-firm
7 Mathews, K. H. Jr., W. F. Hahn, K. E. Nelson,
L. A. Duewer, and R. A. Gustafson. April 1999. U.S.
Beef Industry: Cattle Cycles, Price Spreads, and
Packer Concentration. U.S. Department of
Agriculture, Market and Trade Economics Division,
Economic Research Service. Technical Bulletin No.
1874.
8 Federal Trade Commission. 1918. Annual
Report for 1918, p. 23., available at ftc_ar_1918.pdf
(last accessed 8/9/2022).
9 Id.
10 United States v. Swift & Co., Equity No. 37623,
(Sup. Ct. of D.C. 1920).
11 Harl, Agricultural Law, sec. 71.03 (1993).
12 MacDonald, J.M., M. E. Ollinger, K. E. Nelson,
and C. R. Handy. Consolidation in U.S.
Meatpacking. Food and Rural Economics Division,
Economic Research Service, U.S. Department of
Agriculture. Agricultural Economic Report No. 785.
Available at https://www.ers.usda.gov/publications/
pub-details/?pubid=41120, accessed 9/19/22.
PO 00000
Frm 00003
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
60011
concentration ratio grew from 36
percent to 81 percent in beef packing
(steers and heifers) and rose by 34
percent to 64 percent in hogs.13 Between
1977 and 2020, the four-firm
concentration ratio in the poultry broiler
industry increased from 22 percent to 53
percent.14
The above data reflects the state of
concentration nationally, but
concentration in local markets that
exceeds national averages has been
observed in the poultry, hog and pig,
and cattle industries. In the last
available survey of local markets (2011),
MacDonald and Key found that about
one quarter of contract growers reported
that there was just one live poultry
dealer in their area; another quarter
reported two; another quarter reported
three; and the rest reported four or
more.15 Regional concentration is often
higher than national concentration for
hogs.16 And in cattle, based on AMS’s
experience conducting investigations
and monitoring markets, there are
commonly only one or two buyers in
some local geographic markets, and few
sellers have the option of selling fed
cattle to more than three or four packers.
The move towards heightened
concentration was accompanied by a
dramatic shift from the spot market
towards various types of vertical
contracts. In the early 20th century,
farm-finished cattle and hogs were
primarily shipped by rail and
slaughtered in urban centers close to
large consumer bases, and fresh meat
was rail-shipped only by the largest
packers. Prices for cattle and hog
purchases were largely negotiated in
spot, cash markets in person. In 1921,
poultry consumption accounted for a
small share of total U.S. meat
consumption, and retail distribution
outlets (i.e., local food markets) were not
centralized.
13 U.S. Department of Agriculture, Agricultural
Marketing Service., Packers and Stockyards
Division, Annual Report. Various years.
14 U.S. Department of Agriculture, Agricultural
Marketing Service, Packers and Stockyards
Division, Annual Report, 2020. 2021 draft pending
as of 07/11/22. United States Department of
Agriculture Grain Inspection, Packers and
Stockyards Administration. ‘‘Assessment of the
Livestock and Poultry Industries Fiscal Year 2007.’’
May 2008.
15 MacDonald, James M. ‘‘Technology,
Organization, and Financial Performance in U.S.
Broiler Production,’’ EIB–126, U.S. Department of
Agriculture, Economic Research Service, June 2014.
16 Wise, T. A., S. E. Trist. ‘‘Buyer Power in U.S.
Hog Markets: A Critical Review of the Literature,’’
Tufts University, Global Development and
Environment Institute (GDAE) Working Paper No.
10–04, August 2010, available at: https://
sites.tufts.edu/gdae/files/2020/03/1004HogBuyerPower.pdf.TAbl (last accessed 8/9/
2022).
E:\FR\FM\03OCP3.SGM
03OCP3
60012
Federal Register / Vol. 87, No. 190 / Monday, October 3, 2022 / Proposed Rules
lotter on DSK11XQN23PROD with PROPOSALS3
In successive decades, as
concentration in the industry increased
and as the size of plants increased, large
packers needed to ensure constant and
secure supplies of animals to keep these
larger plants running at peak capacity.17
Buying animals through contracts with
producers was believed to facilitate
their ability to do so. Vertical contracts
took the form of production, marketing,
and forward contracts.
Livestock and poultry production
contracts are agreements between a
producer and a contractor, where the
livestock (generally hogs) or poultry are
grown by a grower on behalf of the
contractor under specific guidelines
(production practices or target weight,
for example) identified in the contract.
The producer is generally paid a
contract fee by the contractor for
growing the livestock or poultry. Once
the livestock or poultry reach a specific
weight, they are often marketed to a
packer or live poultry dealer under a
marketing contract, though they could
also be marketed on the spot market.
Under a marketing contract, the
ownership of the livestock or poultry
(mostly livestock) remains with the
producer until they are ready to be
marketed to a packer or live poultry
dealer. A marketing contract is an
agreement between a producer and a
packer or live poultry dealer that
identifies a price (or a pricing formula),
quantities/qualities, and a delivery
schedule for the livestock or poultry to
the packer or live poultry dealer. A
forward contract is a specific type of
marketing contract (generally for
livestock) under which a specific group
of livestock is negotiated for sale by a
producer or contractor to a packer
several months in advance of delivery of
the livestock. The producer or
contractor and packer agree to the
delivery month and pricing method for
the specific group of livestock to be
delivered. The producer generally picks
the day of delivery in the delivery
month.
The growth of these vertical contract
relationships, in the context of highly
concentrated markets, has led to
concerns that firms have greater control
17 MacDonald. J. M. and W. D. McBride. The
Transformation of U.S. Livestock Agriculture: Scale,
Efficiency, and Risks. January 2009. Economic
Information Bulletin No. (EIB–43). Available at
https://www.ers.usda.gov/webdocs/publications/
44292/10992_eib43.pdf?v=0, accessed 9–20–2022.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
20:25 Sep 30, 2022
Jkt 259001
over producers and thus have more
ability to abuse their market power,
impede producer choices, exclude some
market participants, and coerce
producers unwittingly into inefficient
farm decisions.18 Many have expressed
concern that the decline in the use of
spot markets to market livestock has
also led to harder-to-quantify losses of
independent ways of life, adversely
impacting rural economies and
communities.19
Among the four major meat markets,
chicken companies adopted production
contracting earliest and most
completely. Between 1950 and 1955,
along with increased vertical integration
through ownership of the flocks, the use
of production contracts rose from 5 to
85 percent of the broiler industry’s
production to become nearly universal
by 1975. The same switch was slower in
turkey production, exceeding 80 percent
in 1977.20 The share of hogs sold
through long-term marketing contracts
increased from 10 to 72 percent between
1993 and 2001. Packer-owned hogs
increased from 6.4 percent of U.S. hog
production in 1994 to 24 percent in
18 Hendrickson, M.K., and H.S. James, Jr. 2005.
‘‘The Ethics of Constrained Choice: How the
Industrialization of Agriculture Impacts Farming
and Farmer Behavior.’’ Journal of Agricultural and
Environmental Ethics, 18: 269–291. In:
Hendrickson, M., James, H., Heffernan, W.D. 2013.
‘‘Vertical Integration and Concentration in U.S.
Agriculture.’’ In: Thompson, P., Kaplan, D. (eds)
Encyclopedia of Food and Agricultural Ethics.
Springer, Dordrecht, 7. See also Christopher
Leonard, ‘‘The Meat Racket’’ (2015); C. Robert
Taylor, ‘‘Harvested Cattle, Slaughtered Markets,’’
April 27, 2022, available at https://www.antitrust
institute.org/work-product/aai-advisor-roberttaylor-issues-new-analysis-on-the-market-powerproblem-in-beef-lays-out-new-policy-framework-forensuring-competition-and-fairness-in-cattle-andbeef-markets/; Peter Carstensen, ‘‘Buyer Power and
the Horizontal Merger Guidelines: Minor Progress
on an Important Issue,’’ 14 U. Pa. J. Bus. L. 775
(2012), available at https://repository.law.wisc.edu/
s/uwlaw/item/29746.
19 James, H.S. Jr., M.K. Hendrickson, and P.H.
Howard. 2013. ‘‘Networks, Power and Dependency
in the Agrifood Industry.’’ In H.S. James, Jr. (ed.),
‘‘The Ethics and Economics of Agrifood
Competition’’ (pp. 99–126). Dordrecht, The
Netherlands: Springer Publishers. In: Hendrickson,
M., James, H., Heffernan, W.D. 2013. ‘‘Vertical
Integration and Concentration in US Agriculture.’’
In: Thompson, P., Kaplan, D. (eds) Encyclopedia of
Food and Agricultural Ethics. Springer, Dordrecht,
8.
20 Martinez, S. W. (2002). ‘‘Vertical Coordination
of Marketing Systems: Lessons From the Poultry,
Egg, and Pork Industries.’’ (No. 1473–2016–120694)
Economic Research Service, USDA, Washington,
DC.
PO 00000
Frm 00004
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
2000.21 Comparatively, in the cattle
industry 32 percent of production was
under contract in 2013—referring again
to contractual agreements for growing
cattle to a certain weight or under a
certain production method.22 23
Marketing contracts have seen far
greater adoption. Cattle being marketed
through forward contracts and
Alternative Marketing Arrangements
(AMAs), where cattle are already
dedicated to certain packers or endbuyers, have risen from about 35
percent in 2005 to 73 percent today.24
As a result, since 2005, negotiated cash
trades have declined from 65 percent to
about 27 percent today.25
Some of these developments were
driven in part by technological and
marketing changes.26 In cattle, for
example, the development of boxed beef
to ship standardized cuts allowed
packers to move their slaughter facilities
closer to producers. With cattle no
longer shipped from terminal auction
markets to the large cities, packers
played a more dominant role in the
procurement of cattle directly from
producers within a surrounding area,
and marketing practices shifted, for a
time, towards bilateral cash negotiation
and, then eventually, longer-term
marketing contracts with pricing
formulas.27
21 Martinez, S. W. (2002). ‘‘Vertical Coordination
of Marketing Systems: Lessons From the Poultry,
Egg, and Pork Industries’’ (No. 1473–2016–120694)
Economic Research Service, USDA, Washington,
DC.
22 Crespi, John, and Tina L. Saitone. (2018) ‘‘Are
Cattle Markets the Last Frontier? Vertical
Coordination in Animal-Based Procurement
Markets.’’ Annual Review of Resource Economics
10(1): 207–227.
23 Macdonald, James M. (2015) ‘‘Trends in
Agricultural Contracts.’’ Choices 30(3):1–6.
24 Packers and Stockyards Division, ‘‘Annual
Report’’ (2020).
25 U.S. Department of Agriculture, Agricultural
Marketing Service, Market News, as of May 2022.
26 Lonergan, S. M., and D. N. Marple. ‘‘Historical
perspectives of the meat and animal industry and
their relationship to animal growth, body
composition, and meat technology,’’ ‘‘The Science
of Animal Growth and Meat Technology.’’
Lonergan, S. M., D. N. Marple, Eds., Second
Edition, Elsevier, (2019) 1–17, available at The
Science of Animal Growth and Meat Technology |
ScienceDirect.
27 Lawrence, J.D., Schroeder, T.C. and Hayenga,
M.L. (2001), ‘‘Evolving Producer-Packer-Customer
Linkages in the Beef and Pork Industries.’’ Applied
Economic Perspectives and Policy, 23: 370–385.
Available at https://doi.org/10.1111/14679353.00067.
E:\FR\FM\03OCP3.SGM
03OCP3
Federal Register / Vol. 87, No. 190 / Monday, October 3, 2022 / Proposed Rules
lotter on DSK11XQN23PROD with PROPOSALS3
The increased use of long-term
production and marketing contracts in
livestock and poultry markets, can foster
greater vertical coordination, and
potentially allows certain production
and marketing efficiencies related to
scale and certain enhanced aspects of
packer, or even retailer, control over
product differentiation. The use of
vertical contracts may be appealing to
livestock or poultry producers for a
range of reasons, including more secure
access to markets. In poultry markets,
for example, contracts shift some
aspects of market risks from producers
to live poultry dealers, such as grain
prices or certain weather-related risks.28
In the case of livestock, contracts can
also reduce a producer’s output price
risk.29
On the other hand, as they facilitate
packers and live poultry dealers’ control
across the supply chain, contracts can
shift certain risks onto or between
producers.30 In particular, without
robust open spot markets, cattle
producers have complained of less
ability to enter the markets and less
competition between buyers for better
prices.31 As one notable commentator
28 Knoeber, Charles R., and Walter N. Thurman.
(1995) ‘‘Don’t Count Your Chickens. . . : Risk and
Risk Shifting in the Broiler Industry.’’ American
Journal of Agricultural Economics 77(3): 486–496.
29 Key, N. and MacDonald, J.M. (2006)
‘‘Agricultural Contracting: Trading Autonomy for
Risk Reduction’’ Amber Waves, U.S. Department of
Agriculture Economic Research Service. https://
www.ers.usda.gov/amber-waves/2006/february/
agricultural-contracting-trading-autonomy-for-riskreduction/
30 See, e.g., Michael Kades, ‘‘Protecting Livestock
Producers and Chicken Growers,’’ Washington
Center for Equitable Growth (May 5, 2022),
available at https://equitablegrowth.org/researchpaper/protecting-livestock-producers-and-chickengrowers/; Mary K. Hendrickson, et al., ‘‘The Food
System: Concentration and Its Impacts,’’ A Special
Report for Farm Family Action Alliance, May 2021,
available at https://farmaction.us/
concentrationreport/; C. Robert Taylor, ‘‘Harvested
Cattle, Slaughtered Markets,’’ April 27, 2022,
available at https://www.antitrustinstitute.org/workproduct/aai-advisor-robert-taylor-issues-newanalysis-on-the-market-power-problem-in-beef-laysout-new-policy-framework-for-ensuringcompetition-and-fairness-in-cattle-and-beefmarkets/; Peter Carstensen, ‘‘Buyer Power and the
Horizontal Merger Guidelines: Minor Progress on an
Important Issue,’’ 14 U. Pa. J. Bus. L. 775 (2012),
available at https://repository.law.wisc.edu/s/
uwlaw/item/29746.
31 See, e.g., Bill Bullard, ‘‘Chronically Besieged:
The U.S. Live Cattle Industry,’’ Presentation to
Thurman Arnold Project at Yale and Law, Ethics,
& Animals Program at Yale Law School, ‘‘Big Ag &
Antitrust Conference,’’ Jan. 2021, available at
https://www.r-calfusa.com/wp-content/uploads/
2021/01/210116-Chronically-Beseiged-The-U.S.Live-Cattle-Industry-Final.pdf; see also Nathan
Miller et al., ‘‘Buyer Power in the Beef Packing
Industry: An Update on Research in Progress,’’
April 2022, available at https://
www.nathanhmiller.org/cattlemarkets.pdf.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:24 Sep 30, 2022
Jkt 259001
has termed them, these markets appear
to be by ‘‘invitation only.’’ 32
Limited options for producers
heighten the risks of prejudicial
exclusion and retaliation. Over the
years, these concerns have been
reported to USDA, but the Department
has not been able to effectively address
complaints, in part owing to insufficient
clarity around P&S Act rules and
standards and related questions around
the ability for individuals to bring cases
based on specific instances of harm.
The rise of concentrated and
vertically integrated markets also gives
rise to certain abuses that may take the
form of deception. For example, cattle
producers have complained to USDA
that they are provided with false
pretexts as to why a packer would not
accept cattle from a producer or would
pay less for it. Similarly, poultry and
swine growers have complained they
have not been told the truth regarding
why they were terminated from
contracts or otherwise treated
differently under them. These forms of
deception may also be connected with
efforts to discriminate, retaliate, or
otherwise unjustly exclude certain
producers or growers from the
marketplace.33
Concerns with the rise of vertically
integrated contracting across
concentrated markets were highlighted
in a series of workshops conducted by
the U.S. Department of Justice (DOJ) and
USDA in 2010.34 And indeed, following
the workshops, a number of producers
reported to USDA that they suffered
retaliation, and that racial and other
exclusionary prejudices were problems.
In 2010 and 2016, USDA proposed
regulations seeking to address many of
these concerns, given their
pervasiveness in the marketplace and
the longstanding challenges that USDA
faced in addressing them. However, the
relevant provisions of the proposed
regulations were not finalized.35
Unfortunately, the concentrated
nature of livestock and poultry markets
32 C. Robert Taylor, ‘‘The Many Faces of
Corporate Power in the Food System.’’ Presented at
DOJ/FTC Workshop on Merger Enforcement,
February 2004, available at https://www.justice.gov/
atr/many-faces-power-food-system.
33 See, e.g., ‘‘Transition Recommendations: On
Issues Related to Agricultural Concentration and
Competition,’’ Campaign for Contract Agriculture
Reform . . . Western Organization of Resource
Councils, et al., Nov. 9, 2020.
34 Department of Justice. ‘‘Competition and
Agriculture: Voices from the Workshops on
Agriculture and Antitrust Enforcement in our 21st
Century Economy and Thoughts on the Way
Forward.’’ May 2012. Available at https://
www.justice.gov/sites/default/files/atr/legacy/2012/
05/16/283291.pdf.
35 Poultry Grower Ranking Systems; Withdrawal
of Proposed Rule, 86 FR 60779 (November 4, 2021).
PO 00000
Frm 00005
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
60013
exposes all producers to potential
market abuses, but some may not be
well positioned to protect themselves.
Racial and ethnic minorities are
arguably more exposed to market
abuses, as evidenced by their
participation in the agricultural sector
having declined sharply over the last
many decades. The most recent data
from the 2017 Census of Agriculture
(Figures 1 and 2) indicate that nonwhite racial and ethnic groups
constitute a very small share of
contracted livestock and poultry
producers—a trend likely due in part to
historical discrimination against these
groups.
Undoubtedly, discrimination such as
what has been experienced by these
groups in the past continues in some
form today, which is why additional
protections are needed. Further, the
same USDA Census of Agriculture data
show that producers who identify as
Black and Native Hawaiian are more
likely to have lower gross revenue than
their white counterparts, which makes
these producers relatively more
vulnerable to the market abuses
observed in the sector today. These
longstanding challenges have prompted
Congress and USDA to promote more
equitable market access. Section II.B.ii,
below provides a more extensive
discussion of AMS’s concerns regarding
the exclusion from, or disadvantages in,
certain markets.
Retaliation remains a prevalent
concern in today’s concentrated and
highly integrated markets. For example,
as recently as April 2022, threats and
fear of retaliation interfered with plans
for invited witnesses to testify at each of
the House and Senate Agriculture
Committees’ hearings on livestock
competition practices. In his opening
remarks, House Agriculture Committee
Chair David Scott noted:
We were supposed to have a 4th
witness, a rancher, on our panel, but
due to intimidation and threats to this
person’s livelihood, to this person’s
reputation, they chose not to participate
out of fear. Witness intimidation is
unacceptable. . .
Only a day before, Senator Deborah
Fischer had stated:
I wish we had a Nebraska producer
here, but as is noted in their letter, none
of our producer members we
encouraged to testify were willing to put
themselves out front for fear of possible
retribution from other market
participants, an unfortunate reality of
today’s cattle industry.36
36 House Chair David Scott D–GA, Opening
remarks, U.S. House, Committee on Agriculture,
E:\FR\FM\03OCP3.SGM
Continued
03OCP3
60014
Federal Register / Vol. 87, No. 190 / Monday, October 3, 2022 / Proposed Rules
lotter on DSK11XQN23PROD with PROPOSALS3
Producer organizations have also
recently reported to USDA concerns
relating to possible coercion in the
rulemaking comment process.37 Section
II, and in particular II.E.ii, below,
provide a more fulsome discussion of
concerns regarding retaliation for
engaging in protected activities.
Deception in various forms and guises
also remains a concern in the
marketplace, including during the
COVID–19 pandemic, where producers
had dramatically reduced access to
markets.38 We discuss these concerns
extensively in Section III, below.
The historic Executive order issued by
the Biden-Harris administration,
Executive Order (E.O.) 14036—
Promoting Competition in the American
Economy (86 FR 36987; July 9, 2021),
directs the Secretary of Agriculture to
address unfair treatment of farmers and
improve conditions of competition in
their markets by considering rulemaking
to address, among other things, certain
practices related to market abuses and
enhanced competition in the livestock,
poultry, and related markets, including
unjustly discriminatory, unduly
prejudicial, and deceptive practices, in
particular retaliation. E.O. 14036 also
underscored that an individual should
not have to show market-wide harm to
secure relief under the Act. AMS has
considered that direction in undertaking
this rulemaking.
The P&S Act is a remedial statute
enacted to address problems faced by
farmers, producers, and other
participants in certain livestock,
poultry, and related agricultural
‘‘An Examination of Price Discrepancies,
Transparency, and Alleged Unfair Practices in
Cattle Markets,’’ April 27, 2022, (14 min: 24 sec),
available at https://anchor.fm/houseagdems/
episodes/An-Examination-of-Price-DiscrepanciesTransparency-and-Alleged-Unfair-Practices-inCattle-Markets-e1hpvo8/a-a7r40dk. U.S. Senate
Committee on Agriculture, Nutrition, and Forestry,
‘‘Legislative hearing to review S. 4030, the Cattle
Price Discovery and Transparency Act of 2022, and
S. 3870, the Meat and Poultry Special Investigator
Act of 2022,’’ April 26, 2022 (1 hour 39 min),
available at https://www.agriculture.senate.gov/
hearings/legislative-hearing-to-review-s-4030-thecattle-price-discovery-and-transparency-act-of2022-and-s3870-the-meat-and-poultry-specialinvestigator-act-of-2022.
37 See, e.g., U.S. Department of Agriculture,
‘‘USDA Extends Public Comment Period to August
23 and Posts Public Webinar for the Proposed Rule
to Promote Transparency in Poultry Grower
Contracting and Tournaments,’’ Aug. 5, 2022,
available at https://www.usda.gov/media/pressreleases/2022/08/05/usda-extends-public-commentperiod-august-23-and-posts-public (last accessed
Aug. 2022).
38 On limits to market access in the pandemic, see
U.S. Department of Agriculture, Agricultural
Marketing Service, ‘‘Agricultural Competition: A
Plan in Support of Fair and Competitive Markets,’’
May 2022, available at https://www.ams.usda.gov/
reports/agricultural-competition-plan-support-fairand-competitive-markets (last accessed Aug. 2022).
VerDate Sep<11>2014
20:25 Sep 30, 2022
Jkt 259001
markets; to protect the public from
predatory practices; and to help ensure
a stable food supply. Thus, as academics
and courts have noted, the Act has ‘‘tortlike provisions that are concerned with
unfair practices and discrimination’’
that fulfill a ‘‘market facilitating
function,’’ which Congress designed to
prevent ‘‘market abuse.’’ 39 AMS
interprets and implements the Act to
affect its core statutory purposes.40 AMS
is concerned that the current regulations
do not adequately address many unduly
prejudicial, unjustly discriminatory, and
deceptive practices, which are
exacerbated by increased horizontal
concentration and vertical contracting.
This proposed rule aims to address
those concerns.
B. Previous Rulemakings
At the direction of Congress, through
the Food, Conservation, and Energy Act
of 2008 (2008 Farm Bill) (Pub. L. 110–
246), USDA’s then Grain Inspection,
Packers, and Stockyards Administration
(GIPSA), which administered the
Packers and Stockyards Act, published
a proposed rule (75 FR 35338; June 22,
2010) (2010 Proposed Rule).41 The 2010
Proposed Rule, among other things,
banned retaliation as an ‘‘unfair,
unjustly discriminatory, and deceptive
practice,’’ and clarified when certain
conduct in the livestock and poultry
industries represents the making or
giving of an undue or unreasonable
preference or advantage or subjects a
39 Herbert Hovenkamp, ‘‘Does the Packers and
Stockyards Act Require Antitrust Harm?’’ (2011).
Faculty Scholarship at Penn Carey Law. 1862.
https://scholarship.law.upenn.edu/faculty_
scholarship/1862 (‘‘subsections (a) and (b) appear to
be tort-like provisions that are concerned with
unfair practices and discrimination, but not with
restraint of trade or monopoly as such’’); Peter
Carstensen, The Packers and Stockyards Act: A
History of Failure to Date, CPI Antitrust Journal 2–
7 (April 2010) (‘‘Congress sought to ensure that the
practices of buyers and sellers in livestock (and
later poultry) markets were fair, reasonable, and
transparent. This goal can best be described as
market facilitating regulation.’’); Michael C. Stumo
& Douglas J. O’Brien, Antitrust Unfairness vs.
Equitable Unfairness in Farmer/Meat Packer
Relationships, 8 Drake J. Agric. L. 91 (2003);
Michael Kades, ‘‘Protecting livestock producers and
chicken growers,’’ Washington Center for Equitable
Growth (May 2022), https://equitablegrowth.org/
wp-content/uploads/2022/05/050522-packersstockyards-report.pdf (‘‘Section 202’s prohibitions
on unjust discrimination and undue preference are
not limited to conduct that destroys or limits
competition or creates a monopoly. These
provisions address conduct that impedes a wellfunctioning market and deprives livestock and
poultry producers of the true value of their animals.
Taken together, these provisions seek to prevent
market abuses.’’).
40 See Bowman v. U.S. Dep’t of Agric., 363 F.2d
81 at 85 (5th Cir. 1966).
41 In 2017, GIPSA merged with the Agricultural
Marketing Service (AMS). AMS now administers
the regulations under the Act and undertook this
rulemaking to meet the statutory requirement.
PO 00000
Frm 00006
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
person or locality to an undue or
unreasonable prejudice or disadvantage.
Congress then prohibited finalization of
portions of the 2010 Proposed Rule
through appropriations acts for fiscal
years 2012 through 2015.
In 2015, after increased public
awareness of issues that the 2010
Proposed Rule attempted to address,42
Congress ceased including the
prohibition in appropriations bills, and
GIPSA undertook another rulemaking to
address these issues. In 2016, the agency
published another proposed rule (81 FR
92703; December 20, 2016) (2016
Proposed Rule) attempting to establish
what constituted unfair practices and
undue preferences, along with a related
interim final rule (81 FR 92566) (2016
IFR). Following the change of
administration, the agency decided to
take no further action on the rule. In a
notification of no further action
published in the Federal Register (82
FR 48603; October 18, 2017) (2017 No
Further Action Notification), GIPSA
acknowledged that some producers,
growers, and farm trade groups
generally supported the proposed rule,
and many commenters had raised
concerns about growing power
imbalances, discrimination, and
retaliation. GIPSA, however, decided
not to finalize the 2016 Proposed Rule,
in part on the grounds that it raised the
stakes for regulated entities in ways that
could suppress innovation, and
contained ambiguous terms that were
likely to increase and prolong litigation
between producers and regulated
entities and between regulated entities
and AMS. The 2016 Proposed Rule
listed six non-exclusive criteria for the
Secretary to consider when determining
whether conduct constituted an unfair
practice or preference. In contrast, the
current proposed rule focuses on
discrimination, deception, and
retaliation.
In 2020, AMS issued a proposed rule
(85 FR 1771; January. 13, 2020) (2020
Proposed Rule), which was finalized
later that year (85 FR 79779; December.
11, 2020) (2020 Final Rule), which that
set out several (nonexclusive) criteria
the Secretary would consider
concerning undue or unreasonable
preferences or advantages: whether the
preference or advantage cannot be
justified on the basis of a cost savings
related to dealing with different
producers, sellers, or growers; cannot be
justified on the basis of meeting a
42 ‘‘Chickens: Last Week Tonight with John
Oliver,’’ HBO, May 17, 2015, available at https://
www.youtube.com/watch?v=X9wHzt6gBgI; see also
Nathaniel Haas, ‘‘John Oliver v. chicken,’’ Politico,
June 1, 2015, available at https://www.politico.com/
story/2015/06/john-oliver-vs-chicken-118510.
E:\FR\FM\03OCP3.SGM
03OCP3
Federal Register / Vol. 87, No. 190 / Monday, October 3, 2022 / Proposed Rules
lotter on DSK11XQN23PROD with PROPOSALS3
competitor’s prices; cannot be justified
on the basis of meeting other terms
offered by a competitor; and cannot be
justified as a reasonable business
decision. In response to the 2020
Proposed Rule, AMS received numerous
comments raising concerns regarding
discriminatory and retaliatory practices;
however, AMS stated that the 2020
Final Rule was intended for the
narrower purpose of establishing criteria
to consider.43 Specifically, the 2020
Proposed Rule’s preamble noted that
discrimination on the basis of race,
gender, and other such protected bases
was unlawful and would be addressed
as potential violations of the Act’s
prohibition against undue prejudices. In
August 2021, AMS reiterated this policy
in a series of Frequently Asked
Questions (FAQs).44 AMS’s FAQs also
underscored that the rule’s criteria were
‘‘not exhaustive and not determinative.’’
In the context of each of these
rulemakings spanning the last decade,
GIPSA, and later AMS, received
comments regarding the power
imbalances in the livestock and poultry
industries and highlighting the need for
regulations that adequately protect
farmers against recurrent retaliation,
deception, and discrimination. Given
the consistency of these assertions, as
well as the concerns further brought to
light during the COVID–19 pandemic
regarding today’s increasingly
concentrated livestock and poultry
markets,45 AMS believes this proposed
rule is needed to effectuate its
responsibility to protect producers
against unlawful practices that exclude,
disadvantage, discriminate against,
retaliate against, or deceive them, and
that the rulemaking would promote
markets with integrity that are
competitive and inclusive to all.
43 Undue and Unreasonable Preferences and
Advantages Under the Packers and Stockyards Act,
85 FR 79779 (January 11, 2021), 9 CFR part 201.
Comments available at https://www.regulations.gov/
document/AMS-FTPP-18-0101-0001/comment.
44 85 FR 79779; U.S. Department of Agriculture,
Agricultural Marketing Service, ‘‘Frequently Asked
Questions on the Enforcement of Undue and
Unreasonable Preferences under the Packers and
Stockyards Act,’’ August 2021, available at https://
www.ams.usda.gov/rules-regulations/packers-andstockyards-act/faq (last accessed June 2022).
45 U.S. Department of Agriculture, ‘‘Agri-Food
Supply Chain Assessment: Program and Policy
Options for Strengthening Resilience,’’ 12–17,
February 2021, available at https://
www.ams.usda.gov/supply-chain (last accessed
Aug. 2022); see also Agricultural Marketing Service,
U.S. Department of Agriculture, ‘‘Agricultural
Competition: A Plan in Support of Fair and
Competitive Markets,’’ May 2022, available at
https://www.ams.usda.gov/reports/agriculturalcompetition-plan-support-fair-and-competitivemarkets (last accessed Aug. 2022).
VerDate Sep<11>2014
20:25 Sep 30, 2022
Jkt 259001
II. Undue Prejudices or Disadvantages
and Unjust Discriminatory Practices
A. Agency Interpretation of Undue or
Unreasonable Prejudice or
Disadvantage and Unjust
Discriminatory Practices
This proposed rule addresses
concerns related to undue prejudices or
disadvantages and unjust
discrimination. First, proposed
§ 201.304(a) would establish clearer
duties on packers, swine contractors,
and live poultry dealers to ensure full
and non-discriminatory market access
for market vulnerable individuals. This
section would also prohibit undue
prejudices and disadvantages against
cooperatives.
Second, proposed § 201.304(b) would
address retaliation by setting out
protected activities that a covered
producer may engage in but that a
regulated entity may not use as grounds
for unjust discrimination or undue
prejudice or disadvantage. The
proposed regulations would prohibit
regulated entities from retaliating
against a covered producer for
participating in a protected activity by
terminating a contract, refusing to renew
a contract, offering more unfavorable
contract terms than those generally or
ordinarily offered, refusing to deal,
interfering with third-party contracts,
and other actions with a an adverse
impact to covered producers. These acts
of retaliation would be unjustly
discriminatory and unduly prejudicial
and disadvantageous.
Section 202(b) of the P&S Act (7
U.S.C. 192(b)) prohibits regulated
entities from ‘‘subjecting any particular
person or locality to any undue or
unreasonable prejudice or disadvantage
in any respect[.]’’ Though not defined
by the Act, in 1921, legal definitions of
prejudice included anything that
‘‘places the person affected in a more
unfavorable or disadvantageous position
than he would otherwise have
occupied.’’ 46 Merriam-Webster.com
defines prejudice to include ‘‘injury or
damage resulting from some judgment
or action of another in disregard of one’s
rights’’ and ‘‘an irrational attitude of
hostility directed against an individual,
a group, a race, or their supposed
characteristics.’’ 47 USDA’s Judicial
Officer has defined prejudice in an
administrative adjudication as
‘‘subjecting any person to any injury or
damage and not subjecting all similarly
46 Roberto v. Catino, 140 Md. 38, 116 A. 873, 875
(1922).
47 Merriam-Webster online dictionary, https://
www.merriam-webster.com/dictionary/prejudice
(accessed June 15, 2022).
PO 00000
Frm 00007
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
60015
situated persons to the same injury or
damage [.]’’ 48
Likewise, sec. 202(a) of the P&S Act
(7 U.S.C. 192(a)) prohibits ‘‘unjust
discrimination.’’ but does not expressly
define the term. Merriam-Webster.com
defines ‘‘unjust’’ as: ‘‘characterized by
injustice: unfair.’’ 49 The common
meaning of the word ‘‘discrimination’’
means ‘‘differential treatment;
especially a failure to treat all persons
equally where no reasonable distinction
can be found between those favored and
those not favored.’’ 50 While the
meaning of the word ‘‘discriminatory’’
varies depending on the context, the
common definition includes ‘‘applying
or favoring discrimination in
treatment.’’ 51 Therefore, under sec.
202(a) of the Act, a regulated entity
treating similar entities differently with
respect to livestock, meats, meat food
products, livestock products in
unmanufactured form, or live poultry
based on certain conditions is an
unjustly discriminatory practice.52
The terms ‘‘unjust discrimination’’
and ‘‘undue or unreasonable prejudice
or disadvantage’’ in the P&S Act do not
follow the precise language of any law
that preceded it. This is not without
reason. The P&S Act ‘‘would never have
been adopted by the Congress if the
marketing of livestock and the
distribution of meat products did not
present problems [that] were
insufficiently met by the [then existing]
antitrust laws[.]’’ 53 There were two
laws, however, that preceded the
passage of the P&S Act that influenced
the inclusions of ‘‘unjust
discrimination’’ and ‘‘undue or
unreasonable prejudice or
disadvantage’’ in the P&S Act: the
Clayton Act, and the Interstate
Commerce Act. While both the Clayton
Act and the Interstate Commerce Act
informed the P&S Act’s prohibition on
unfair and discriminatory practices, the
P&S Act has a broader application.
The Clayton Act, passed in 1914, used
the language of discrimination
specifically with respect to
discriminatory pricing, prohibiting
anyone from ‘‘either directly or
48 In Re: IBP, Inc., 57 Agric. Dec. 1353 (U.S.
Department of Agriculture July 31, 1998).
49 Merriam-Webster online dictionary, https://
www.merriam-webster.com/dictionary/unjust
(accessed June 15, 2022).
50 Black’s Law Dictionary, p. 586 (11th ed. 2019).
51 Merriam-Webster online dictionary, https://
www.merriam-webster.com/dictionary/
discriminatory (accessed June 15, 2022).
52 See, also In Re: IBP, Inc., 57 Agric. Dec. 1353
(1998), rev’d on other grounds by Excel Corp. v.
United States Dep’t of Agri., 397 F.3d 1285 (10th
Cir. 2005).
53 Crosse & Blackwell Co. v. F.T.C., 262 F.2d 600,
604 (4th Cir. 1959).
E:\FR\FM\03OCP3.SGM
03OCP3
60016
Federal Register / Vol. 87, No. 190 / Monday, October 3, 2022 / Proposed Rules
lotter on DSK11XQN23PROD with PROPOSALS3
indirectly [discriminating] in price
between different purchasers of
commodities . . . where the effect of
such discrimination may be to
substantially lessen competition or
create a monopoly in any line of
commerce.’’ 54 The Clayton Act was
careful to expressly prohibit
discriminatory pricing in particular. In
contrast, the P&S Act does not include
this textual limitation. In addition, the
Clayton Act requires that the
discrimination ‘‘may be to substantially
effect competition or create a
monopoly.’’ The P&S Act, again, is
broader:
[T]he prohibitions of [the Act] go
further than the prohibitions in the
Clayton Act. For instance, one of the
sections of the Clayton Act prohibits
discrimination in prices as between
localities, and then contains a sort of
nullification clause, to the effect that it
shall not prevent anybody from
choosing his own customers or making
discriminations in prices where there is
a difference in quality or a difference in
transportation charges, and so forth,
while this bill makes any undue or
unreasonable discrimination as between
localities or between persons
unlawful.55
Likewise, the Interstate Commerce
Act was an important template for the
P&S Act. The P&S Act’s statutory
history is replete with references and
comparisons, in general terms, to the
Interstate Commerce Act. Passed in
1887, the Interstate Commerce Act
forbade common carriers—primarily
meaning railroads—from undue
preferences, prejudices, and
discrimination in their rates and charges
between connecting lines.56 As the
Supreme Court explained the Interstate
Commerce Act in 1934: ‘‘The purpose
. . . was to bring into existence a body
which, from its special character, would
be best fitted to determine, among other
things, whether upon the facts in a
given case there is an unjust
discrimination against interstate
commerce.’’ 57
54 The Clayton Act, sec. 2, Public Law No. 63–
212, 38 Stat. 730 (1914).
55 61 Cong. Rec. 1888 (1921) (statement of Rep.
Anderson).
56 Act of February 4, 1887 (Interstate Commerce
Act), sec. 3, Public Law 49–41, February 4, 1887;
Enrolled Acts and Resolutions of Congress, 1789;
General Records of the United States Government,
1778—1992; Record Group 11; National Archives.
57 State of Fla. v. United States, 292 U.S. 1, 12,
54 S. Ct. 603, 608, 78 L. Ed. 1077 (1934) (citing
United States v. Louisville & Nashville R.R. Co., 235
U.S. 314, 320 (1914)).’’[F]rom the beginning the
very purpose for which the Commission was
created was to . . . decide whether from facts,
disputed or undisputed [whether a] preference or
discrimination existed.’’ Louisville and Nashville
R.R. Co., 235 U.S. at 320.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:24 Sep 30, 2022
Jkt 259001
With respect to the courts’
interpretation of unjustly discriminatory
practices under the P&S Act, there are
few Federal cases that explore the
difference between unjust
discrimination and the other provisions
of the Act. Because of the P&S Act’s
similarity to the Clayton Act, the
Seventh Circuit holds that unjust
discrimination has included below-cost
sales which injure sellers or primary
line competition, even if the buyers or
secondary-line competition are not
affected. See Wilson & Co. v. Benson,
286 F.2d 891, 895 (7th Cir. 1961).
Likewise, that circuit holds that price
discrimination in favor of a larger
grocery store chain, and higher prices to
its competitors, are another type of
unjust discrimination that the Act has
prevented. Swift & Co. v. United States,
317 F.2d 53, 55–56 (7th Cir. 1963).
Moreover, the Supreme Court has held
that when discrimination is used as an
attempt to limit competition, it is a
monopoly practice. See Denver Union
Stock Yard Co. v. Producers Livestock
Mktg., 356 U.S. 282, 289 (1958)
(interpreting sec. 312 of the Act and
finding that regulations aimed at
preventing market agencies registered at
one stockyard from doing business for
producers at any other market within a
normal marketing area to be a monopoly
practice).
AMS proposes this regulation to
protect the integrity of the market as a
competitive, price-clearing,
economically open commercial
endeavor by eliminating or restraining
prejudicial discrimination. This
includes prejudicial discriminatory
behaviors such as those that adversely
impact open access by competitors and
market participants (through certain
exclusionary prejudices, such as
denying or disadvantaging an
individual’s access to market on
grounds which could include race,
gender, religion, or other bases; or
retaliatory discrimination for engaging
in certain basic protected activities
closely tied to the basic requirements of
being in the business of livestock,
poultry, and related markets covered
under the Act), and otherwise exert
forms of control or dependency that
limit the economic freedom of those
participating in the market.58 The harms
these proposed regulations aim to
prevent are the kinds of discrimination
(and, as discussed below, deceptive)
practices that dominant firms can use to
58 Michael Kades, ‘‘Protecting Livestock
Producers and Chicken Growers,’’ Washington
Center for Equitable Growth (May 5, 2022),
available at https://equitablegrowth.org/researchpaper/protecting-livestock-producers-and-chickengrowers/.
PO 00000
Frm 00008
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
limit competition and interfere with the
operation of the market, including
across the entire supply chain with
respect to livestock, meats, meat food
products, livestock products in
unmanufactured form, or for any live
poultry dealer with respect to live
poultry.
B. Prohibited Undue Prejudices or
Disadvantages and Unjust
Discrimination—Proposed
§ 201.304(a)(1)
Section 201.301 of the proposed
regulations would protect the integrity
of the market, promoting fairness and
competition by prohibiting undue
prejudices and disadvantages and unjust
discrimination that inhibit inclusive
market access and treatment.
Specifically, proposed § 201.304(a)(1)
would prohibit prejudice, disadvantage,
or the denial or reduction of market
access by regulated entities against
covered producers based on their status,
as defined in the regulation, of being
‘‘market vulnerable’’ producers. This
term is defined as membership in a
group that has been subjected to, or is
at heightened risk of, adversely
differential treatment in the
marketplace. AMS seeks comments on
whether specific groups should be
named in the definition of a market
vulnerable individual as examples of
market vulnerable individuals and, if so,
requests supporting evidence on the
historical treatment of such groups.
AMS also seeks comment on whether,
alternatively, prohibitions on undue
prejudice or disadvantage or unjust
discrimination would best be addressed
by identifying defined protected classes,
and if so, which protected classes. The
intent of the proposed regulation is to
help break down barriers that may serve
to exclude or disadvantage certain
covered producers, while leaving room
for differential treatment based on
legitimate business purposes.
This proposal defines a covered
producer as a livestock producer (as
defined in the regulation at proposed
§ 201.302) or swine production contract
grower or poultry grower as defined in
sec. 2(a) of the Act. While swine
contract producers and poultry growers
are defined in the Act, AMS believes the
Act is properly read to protect livestock
producers from unjustly prejudicial and
discriminatory practices. To effectuate
this purpose, this proposed rule defines
livestock producer as any person
engaged in the raising and caring for
livestock by the producer or another
person, whether the livestock is owned
by the producer or by another person,
but not an employee of the owner of the
livestock. This definition is designed to
E:\FR\FM\03OCP3.SGM
03OCP3
Federal Register / Vol. 87, No. 190 / Monday, October 3, 2022 / Proposed Rules
lotter on DSK11XQN23PROD with PROPOSALS3
capture the vast majority of market
participants who are dependent on
regulated entities to engage in the
livestock business. AMS seeks comment
on whether to limit the definition to
persons engaging in the raising and
caring for livestock in the chain of
slaughter, or whether such limitation is
unnecessary or improperly limits the
coverage of the Act.
The principal purpose of this
proposed approach is to address
prejudices in the marketplace against
producers that are more vulnerable to
such treatment and to stop unjust
discrimination. AMS views
vulnerability to adverse marketplace
treatment to include, but not be limited
to, exclusion or disadvantage on the
basis of race, ethnicity, or sex or gender
prejudices (including discrimination
against an individual for being lesbian,
gay, transgender, or queer), religion,
disability, or age.59 AMS seeks comment
on these bases, and whether there are
other bases for vulnerability to adverse
marketplace treatment.
This proposed rule aims to ensure
more inclusive market competition and
address allegations related to undue
prejudices through enforceable
regulatory prohibitions. The proposed
prohibitions would protect producers at
both individual and market-wide levels
from undue prejudices and
disadvantages and unjust
discrimination—both of which AMS has
determined violate the P&S Act. The
Secretary is empowered under the P&S
Act to address harms in their
incipiency.60 Moreover, given its
experience interacting with producers
and regulated entities, AMS believes
that individual instances of prejudice
and discrimination can have a
cumulative adverse effect on relevant
markets, including the national market.
AMS believes the proposed regulatory
scheme results in a flexible approach to
resolving marketplace vulnerabilities.
AMS’s proposed regulatory approach of
prohibiting unjust discrimination and
undue prejudices and disadvantages
against market vulnerable producers
recognizes that discrimination against
producers may evolve. AMS expects the
59 Supreme Court case law has established that
discriminating against an individual for being
lesbian, gay, transgender or queer is discrimination
on the basis of sex or gender prejudices. Bostock v.
Clayton Cnty., Georgia, 140 S. Ct. 1731, 1741 (2020)
(‘‘[I]t is impossible to discriminate against a person
for being homosexual or transgender without
discriminating against that individual based on
sex.’’).
60 E.g. Bowman v. United States Dep’t of Agric.,
363 F.2d 81, 85 (5th Cir. 1966) (‘‘‘the Act is
designed to ‘* * * prevent potential injury by
stopping unlawful practices in their incipiency.
Proof of a particular injury is not required.’ ’’).
VerDate Sep<11>2014
20:25 Sep 30, 2022
Jkt 259001
proposed definition will be sufficiently
responsive to the particular facts of
given cases and particular markets over
time. AMS is considering issuing
guidance on the proposed regulatory
approach.
AMS is seeking comment on the
definition of ‘‘market vulnerable
producers.’’ AMS’s goal is to
appropriately govern regulated entities’
conduct for the purpose of ensuring
inclusive competition in the
marketplace, grounded in the Act’s
authorities. This includes seeking
comment on whether it should delineate
specific categories of vulnerable
producers on the basis of membership
in groups that have historically been
subject to adverse treatment owing to
racial, ethnic, gender, or religious
prejudices. If so, AMS solicits
supporting evidence regarding the
historical adverse treatment of such
groups.
AMS also seeks comment on the use
of a ‘‘market vulnerable producer’’
approach—rather than a list of protected
classes that may not be discriminated
against—to the regulatory prohibition
against discrimination. In the alternative
to using the market vulnerable producer
approach, the agency is considering
whether this regulation should ban
discrimination against specific classes,
such as on the basis of race, color,
national origin, religion, sex, sexual
orientation, gender identity, age,
disability, marital status, or family
status. Such an approach would differ
from the market vulnerable individual
approach and would instead more
closely follow the civil rights laws that
prohibit prejudicial discrimination
against certain protected classes.
The prohibition on prejudice against
cooperatives also seeks to prevent
barriers to market access for
cooperatives. Congress has long
recognized the need to provide
enhanced protections for cooperatives,
as embodied for example in the
Agricultural Fair Practices Act of 1967
(Pub. L. 90–288), which protects
producers’ rights to form a
cooperative.61
61 For
the purposes of this preamble, a
cooperative is an incorporated or unincorporated
association of producers, with or without capital
stock, formed for mutual benefit of its members.
Farm cooperatives are formed under state, not
Federal law, even though cooperatives have Federal
protections. See James B. Dean & Thomas Earl Geu,
The Uniform Limited Cooperative Association Act:
An Introduction, 13 Drake J. Agric. L. 63, 67 (2008)
(‘‘There is, however, no single type of cooperative.
Although much of the law that has developed
around cooperatives has developed with respect to
agricultural cooperatives, cooperatives exist in
many areas . . . including housing, insurance,
banking, health care, and retail sales, among
others.’’). Cooperatives can both be buyers and
PO 00000
Frm 00009
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
60017
i. Authority Provided by the Act
There is no indication that Congress
intended to exempt any practice of
regulated entities affecting producers
covered under the Act.62 The P&S Act,
through secs. 202(a) and (b), broadly
prohibits certain practices or devices,
including undue or unreasonable
prejudices and disadvantages and unjust
discrimination. Sections 202(a) and (b)
of the Act identify a number of
prohibited actions with respect to
livestock, meats, meat food products, or
livestock products in unmanufactured
form, or for any live poultry dealer with
respect to live poultry. To effectuate
these statutory prohibitions, AMS
proposes to prohibit specific undue and
unreasonable prejudices, disadvantages,
and discrimination against any covered
producer. AMS also seeks comment on
whether to extend these protections to
all persons buying or selling meat and
meat food products in markets under
the jurisdiction of the Act.
In enacting the P&S Act, Congress cast
a wide net to capture all acts of unjust
discrimination and unreasonable
prejudice against any particular person.
The Act’s prohibition of anticompetitive, discriminatory, and
unreasonably prejudicial actions against
a particular person was not a new
statutory concept, as the Interstate
Commerce Act also banned
unreasonable prejudices and
discriminatory practices well before the
enactment of the P&S Act. While a
finding of being within the Interstate
Commerce Act’s (ICA) scope is not a
necessary precondition for a violation of
the P&S Act, the comparison is
nevertheless useful, especially with
respect to the structure and design of
provisions governing undue prejudices.
A comparison is provided in Table 1,
below.
In Mitchell v. U.S., the Supreme Court
decided that the Interstate Commerce
Act prohibited discrimination based on
race. 313 U.S. 80 (1941). The Supreme
Court held that ‘‘it is apparent from the
legislative history of the Interstate
sellers of agricultural products. Cooperatives made
up of sellers, because they jointly fix the prices of
their goods, are legally permitted to market the
products they produce when the cooperative
organization meets the requirements of the CapperVolstead Act (see 7 U.S.C. 291) or the Clayton Act
(see 15 U.S.C. 17).
62 See 7 U.S.C. 193. C.f. Mitchell v. United States,
313 U.S. 80, 94, 61 S. Ct. 873, 877, 85 L. Ed. 1201
(1941) (‘‘We have repeatedly said that it is apparent
from the legislative history of the Act that not only
was the evil of discrimination the principal thing
aimed at, but that there is no basis for the
contention that Congress intended to exempt any
discriminatory action or practice of interstate
carriers affecting interstate commerce which it had
authority to reach.’’).
E:\FR\FM\03OCP3.SGM
03OCP3
60018
Federal Register / Vol. 87, No. 190 / Monday, October 3, 2022 / Proposed Rules
Commerce Act that not only was the
evil of discrimination the principal
thing aimed at, but that there is no basis
for the contention that Congress
intended to exempt any discriminatory
action or practice of interstate carriers
affecting interstate commerce which it
had authority to reach.’’ 63 Further, the
Court isolated a section of the Interstate
Commerce Act and noted that,
‘‘Paragraph 1 of Section 3 of the Act
says explicitly that it shall be unlawful
for any common carrier subject to the
Act ‘to subject any particular person
* * * to any undue or unreasonable
prejudice or disadvantage in any respect
whatsoever.’’ 64 (Emphasis added) The
Court found that unreasonable prejudice
against an individual based on race was
a violation and concluded that, ‘‘the
Interstate Commerce Act expressly
extends its prohibitions to the
subjecting of ‘any particular person’ to
unreasonable discriminations.’’ 65
The P&S Act contains similar but
broader language than the Interstate
Commerce Act sec. 3 in sec. 202, which
reads, ‘‘It shall be unlawful for any
packer or swine contractor with respect
to livestock, meats, meat food products,
or livestock products in
unmanufactured form, or for any live
poultry dealer with respect to live
poultry, to: (a) Engage in or use any
unfair, unjustly discriminatory, or
deceptive practice or device; or (b) Make
or give any undue or unreasonable
preference or advantage to any
particular person or locality in any
respect, or subject any particular person
or locality to any undue or
unreasonable prejudice or disadvantage
in any respect. . .’’ (emphasis added).
Table 1 illustrates where the text
between the two Acts is similar, and
also how the Packers and Stockyards
Act is broader.66
TABLE 1—COMPARISON OF THE INTERSTATE COMMERCE ACT AND THE PACKERS & STOCKYARDS ACT
Interstate Commerce Act (1887 text) Sec. 3.
P&S Act, Section 202 [7 U.S.C.192]. Unlawful practices enumerated
That it shall be unlawful for any common carrier subject to the provisions of this act to make or give any undue or unreasonable preference or advantage to any particular person, company, firm, corporation, or locality, or any particular description of traffic, in any respect whatsoever,
or to subject any particular person, company, firm, corporation, or
locality, or any particular description of traffic, to any undue or unreasonable prejudice or disadvantage in any respect whatsoever.
Every common carrier subject to the provisions of this act . . . shall
not discriminate in their rates and charges between such connecting lines[.] (emphasis added).
It shall be unlawful for any packer or swine contractor with respect to
livestock, meats, meat food products, or livestock products in unmanufactured form, or for any live poultry dealer with respect to live
poultry, to:
(a) Engage in or use any unfair, unjustly discriminatory, or deceptive
practice or device; or
(b) Make or give any undue or unreasonable preference or advantage
to any particular person or locality in any respect, or subject any
particular person or locality to any undue or unreasonable prejudice or disadvantage in any respect; (emphasis added).
As shown in Table 1, unlike the
Interstate Commerce Act, the P&S Act in
secs. 202(a) and (b) prohibits undue or
unreasonable prejudices or
disadvantages as well as deception and
unjust discrimination (without
limitation to discrimination in rates and
charges in particular). In this proposed
rulemaking, AMS incorporates the
language from sec. 202 to prohibit acts
of unreasonable prejudice and to
prevent unreasonable discrimination
including but not limited to the race
discrimination that the Court found to
be violative of the Interstate Commerce
Act in Mitchell.
This proposed regulation sets forth
specific prohibitions on prejudicial or
discriminatory acts or practices against
individuals that are sufficient to
demonstrate violation of the P&S Act
without the need to further establish
broad-based, market-wide prejudicial or
discriminatory outcomes or harms. The
lotter on DSK11XQN23PROD with PROPOSALS3
63 Id.
at 94.
at 95.
65 Id. at 97.
66 For more on the relationship between the
Interstate Commerce Act and the P&S Act in this
area, see Michael Kades, ‘‘Protecting Livestock
Producers and Chicken Growers,’’ Washington
Center for Equitable Growth, at 66 (May 2022)
discussing Wheeler v. Pilgrim’s Pride Corp., 591
F.3d 355, 368–369 (5th Cir 2009) (en banc) (J. Jones
concurring): ‘‘In all the cases discussed by the
64 Id.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
20:25 Sep 30, 2022
Jkt 259001
prohibitions on regulated entities
adversely treating individual producers
set forth in this proposed rule address
the types of harms the P&S Act is
intended to prevent. AMS believes that
preventing broad-based exclusion is
most effectively enforced at the
individual producer level when the
conduct is in its incipiency.67 To further
allow for effective enforcement of the
statute, AMS is also proposing a
recordkeeping requirement to support
evaluation of regulated entity
compliance.
Marketplace integrity and market
access were leading policy goals at the
time of the Act’s passage. ‘‘The primary
purpose of [the P&S Act] is to assure fair
competition and fair-trade practices in
livestock marketing and in the
meatpacking industry . . . The Act
provides that meatpackers subject to its
provisions shall not engage in practices
that restrain commerce or create a
monopoly. They are also prohibited
from engaging in any . . . unjust
discriminatory practice or device. . .’’
(emphasis added). AMS believes that
discrimination in the form of prejudice
or retaliation against a covered producer
on the basis of certain non-economic
prejudices restrains commerce,
including competition, and effects
undue and unjust trade practices by
denying or inhibiting full market access
for producers. These limitations on
market access are contrary to the
primary purposes of the Act—assuring
fair trade practices and competitive
markets that producers can access, as
well as prohibiting unjust
discrimination. For these reasons, AMS
has determined that prejudice on certain
non-economic bases, as set forth under
‘‘market vulnerable individual,’’ is
undue and unjust.
concurrence dealing with both terms [under the
ICA], the defendant faced charges that it treated
customers differently. According to the court,
‘railway companies are only bound to give the same
terms to all persons alike under the same
conditions.’ If the conditions are different, then
different treatment is merited. Further, ‘competition
between rival routes is one of the matters which
may lawfully be considered in making rates.’
Differential treatment driven by competitive forces
is not a violation. Acknowledging that competition
can justify differential treatment of customers is
different than requiring the plaintiff to prove
anticompetitive harm to establish a violation.’’
67 ‘‘[T]he purpose of the Act is to halt unfair trade
practices in their incipiency, before harm has been
suffered.’’ See Farrow v. U.S. Dep’t of Agr., 760 F.2d
211, 215 (8th Cir. 1985) (citing De Jong Packing Co.
v. U.S. Dep’t of Agric., 618 F.2d 1329, 1336–37 (9th
Cir. 1980)); Swift & Co. v. United States, 393 F.2d
247, 252 (7th Cir. 1968); Armour and Company v.
United States, 402 F.2d 712, 723 n. 12 (7th
Cir.1968).
ii. Economic Rationale
PO 00000
Frm 00010
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
E:\FR\FM\03OCP3.SGM
03OCP3
Federal Register / Vol. 87, No. 190 / Monday, October 3, 2022 / Proposed Rules
Undue prejudice is, furthermore, a
market abuse that undermines market
integrity, deprives the producer of the
benefit of the market, and prevents the
producer from obtaining the true market
value of the livestock, or their
services.68 While such a pathway for
harm is sufficient justification for the
rulemaking, prejudicial discrimination
is also anti-competitive and leads to
economic inefficiencies. This section
addresses the economics of these issues,
including by describing the history of
prejudice and discrimination and their
economic consequences in the
agricultural sector and other economic
sectors for market vulnerable
individuals and groups.
Background and History of Economic
Impacts of Prejudice and Unjust
Discrimination in Agricultural and
Other Economic Sectors
While not necessarily tied exclusively
to the operation of livestock markets, it
is well-documented that undue
prejudice has occurred and persists in
agricultural markets and has led to
market abuse. For example, in the
earlier part of the 1900s agricultural
landholders conspired to restrict land
sales and the administration of Federal
farm support programs to Black people,
including those engaged in livestock
production.69 A 1959 paper reported
‘‘significant market discrimination’’
against Black American producers in the
Southern United States.70 The loss of
heirs’ property—land that is passed
down from generation to generation
without a will or other legal
documentation—has been the leading
cause of Black land loss in US
agriculture.71 Some of the loss of heirs’
property was the direct result of
predatory and discriminatory abuse of
partition sales processes and inequities
in access and use of legal and other
estate planning tools among Black
populations.72
68 See
Stafford v. Wallace, 258 U.S. 495 (1922).
Dania V., Darrick Hamilton, Thomas
W. Mitchell, Nathan A. Rosenberg, and Bryce
Wilson Stucki. ‘‘Black Land Loss: 1920–1997.’’ In
AEA Papers and Proceedings, vol. 112, pp. 38–42.
American Economic Association, 2022.
70 Tang, Anthony M. ‘‘Economic development
and changing consequences of race discrimination
in Southern agriculture.’’ Journal of Farm
Economics 41, no. 5 (1959): 1113–1126.
71 U.S. Department of Agriculture, National
Agricultural Library, ‘‘Heirs’ Property,’’ https://
www.nal.usda.gov/farms-and-agriculturalproduction-systems/heirs-property (last accessed
Aug. 2022).
72 Mitchell, Thomas W. 2019. Historic Partition
Law Reform: A Game Changer for Heirs’ Property
lotter on DSK11XQN23PROD with PROPOSALS3
69 Francis,
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:08 Sep 30, 2022
Jkt 259001
The Federal Government also played
a role in discriminatory practices, which
had significant economic consequences
for Black producers especially. Reports
from the U.S. Commission on Civil
Rights in 1965 and 1982 documented
discrimination in the provision of
USDA programs and other prejudicial
factors leading to the decline in Black
farming.73 In the late 1990s, Black
producers won a lawsuit filed against
USDA for engaging in discriminatory
practices in its farm loan programs—
practices which led to financial ruin
and land loss for many Black farmers.74
These, and other widespread
discriminatory practices, help explain
the relative greater decrease in the
number of Black producers over the
course of the twentieth century.75
Indeed, White farm ownership declined
62 percent and Black farm ownership 96
percent between 1930 and 2012.76 Over
the same period, total acres operated by
Whites declined 9 percent and Blacks
by 90 percent.77
Other racial and ethnic minorities
have also been negatively impacted by
prejudicial acts. Latino and Indigenous
Owners. In Heirs’ property and land fractionation:
fostering stable ownership to prevent land loss and
abandonment. https://www.fs.usda.gov/treesearch/
pubs/58543 (last accessed 8/9/2022).
73 U.S. Commission on Civil Rights. 1965. Equal
Opportunity in Farm Programs: An Appraisal of
Services Rendered by Agencies of the U.S.
Department of Agriculture. https://files.eric.ed.gov/
fulltext/ED068206.pdfUS Commission on Civil
Rights. 1982. ‘‘The Decline of Black Farming in
America.’’ https://eric.ed.gov/?id=ED222604.
74 Feder, J. and T. Cowan. 2013. ‘‘Garcia v.
Vilsack: A Policy and Legal Analysis of a USDA
Discrimination Case’’, Congressional Research
Service report number 7–5700, February 22, 2013.
75 Touzeau, Leslie. 2019. ‘‘Being Stewards of
Land Is Our Legacy’: Exploring the Lived
Experiences of Young Black Farmers.’’ Journal of
Agriculture, Food Systems, and Community
Development 8 (4): 1–6. https://doi.org/10.5304/
jafscd.2019.084.007.
76 Francis, Dania V., Darrick Hamilton, Thomas
W. Mitchell, Nathan A. Rosenberg, and Bryce
Wilson Stucki. ‘‘Black Land Loss: 1920–1997.’’ In
AEA Papers and Proceedings, vol. 112, pp. 38–42.
American Economic Association, 2022; Wood, S., &
Gilbert, J. (2000, Spring). Returning AfricanAmerican farmers to the land: Recent trends and a
policy rationale. The Review of Black Political
Economy, 27, 43–64. Available at https://doi.org/
10.1007/BF02717262.
Touzeau, Leslie. 2019. ‘‘‘Being Stewards of Land
Is Our Legacy’: Exploring the Lived Experiences of
Young Black Farmers.’’ Journal of Agriculture, Food
Systems, and Community Development 8 (4): 1–6.
https://doi.org/10.5304/jafscd.2019.084.007.
77 The Agricultural Census figures on farm
operations for 2012 are downloaded from the
National Agricultural Statistics Service’s Quick
Stats and figures from 1930 are from volume 4 of
the 1930 Census, https://agcensus.library.
cornell.edu/census_year/1930-census/.
PO 00000
Frm 00011
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
60019
people farming on reservations lost their
farmland through the same abuses of
partition sale processes as Black
farmers. Between 1900 and 2017, the
percent of all producers identifying as
White increased nine percentages points
to 96 percent, while American Indian or
Alaska Native producers increased by
only 1.3 percentage points, to 2.3
percent.78 Hispanic or Latino farmers
increased by only 2.4 percentage points
between 1920 and 2017, to 3.4 percent.
Racial and ethnic inequities in farmland
ownership and indicators of farmrelated wealth have also been observed
in recent years.79 Concerns have also
been highlighted regarding the
treatment of Asian American and Pacific
Islander poultry growers, in particular
that immigrant communities may not
appreciate the risks of contractual
arrangements due to language barriers.80
Complete foreclosure of market
access, for example through the loss of
land or other capital, has clear adverse
economic outcomes for protected groups
who wish to engage in the agricultural
sector but cannot. At the same time,
discriminatory acts reduce economic
opportunity for individuals in protected
groups who are able to maintain market
access. This not only causes economic
harm to these groups but also has
broader impacts.
Studies documenting these economic
impacts of prejudicial discrimination in
the agricultural sector are relatively
sparse, partly due to data limitations.
However, economic studies focused on
employment practices, financial
transactions, housing, and other markets
outside the agricultural sector
demonstrate how discrimination may
cause economic harm across all types of
markets, including agricultural ones. As
early as the 1950s, economic studies
documented racial wage gaps between
78 Casey, Alyssa R. Racial Equity in U.S. Farming:
Background in Brief 2021. Congressional Research
Service. https://crsreports.congress.gov/product/
pdf/R/R46969.
79 Horst, M., Marion, A. ‘‘Racial, ethnic and
gender inequities in farmland ownership and
farming in the U.S.’’ Agric Hum Values 36, 1–16
(2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10460-018-9883-3.
80 Christopher Leonard, ‘‘The Meat Racket,’’
(2015) and Witt, Howard. ‘‘Hmong poultry farmers
cry foul, sue’’ Chicago Tribune. May 15, 2006.
Available online at: https://www.chicago
tribune.com/news/ct-xpm-2006-05-15-0605150155story.html.
E:\FR\FM\03OCP3.SGM
03OCP3
60020
Federal Register / Vol. 87, No. 190 / Monday, October 3, 2022 / Proposed Rules
lotter on DSK11XQN23PROD with PROPOSALS3
workers.81 Enabled by a lack of
competition among employers, this
discrimination not only had adverse
economic impacts for protected groups
but also for employers who, due to their
own discriminatory actions, ultimately
paid higher wages for some equally
productive workers.82 Recent studies
highlight how racial wealth disparities
reduce labor market competition, since
reduced wealth hinders job search
abilities.83 On the flip side, recent
research shows that increased labor
market participation among racial
minorities and women contributed to
increased economic output during the
second half of the twentieth century.84
Research on the U.S. patent system
finds that racially-motivated violent acts
reduced the number of patents by Black
inventors in the U.S. during the late
1800s and through the middle of the
twentieth century.85 These patents
could have led to new wealth for the
inventors and increased business
investments, potentially contributing to
overall economic growth. In an analysis
of data from the National Survey of
Small Business Finances, Black ledbusinesses were found to have been
more frequently issued loans with
higher interest rates and other
unfavorable terms relative to white or
male-led businesses, which could
reduce productivity and innovation in
the broader economy.86 In housing,
81 Bayer, P., and K. K. Charles. ‘‘Divergent Paths:
A New Perspective on Earnings Differences
Between Black and White Men since 1940.’’ The
Quarterly Journal of Economics (2018), 1459–1501.
Becker, G.S. The Economics of Discrimination. First
Edition, The University of Chicago Press, 1957.
82 Becker, G.S. The Economics of Discrimination.
First Edition, The University of Chicago Press,
1957.
83 Kate Bahn, Mark Stelzner, and Emilie
Openchowski, ‘‘Wage discrimination and the
exploitation of workers in the U.S. labor market,’’
Washington Center for Equitable Growth,
September 2020, available at https://equitable
growth.org/research-paper/wage-discriminationand-the-exploitation-of-workers-in-the-u-s-labormarket/?longform=true.
84 Hsieh et al., ‘‘The Allocation of Talent and U.S.
Economic Growth,’’ 2019, available at https://
onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.3982/
ECTA11427.
85 Cook, Lisa D. ‘‘Violence and economic activity:
evidence from African American patents, 1870–
1940.’’ Journal of Economic Growth 19, no. 2 (2014):
221–257.
86 Laura Alfaro, Ester Faia, and Camelia Minoiu,
‘‘Distributional Consequences of Monetary Policy
Across Races: Evidence from the U.S. Credit
Register’’ April 2022, available at https://
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:08 Sep 30, 2022
Jkt 259001
recent evidence shows that minority
households are steered towards areas
with higher rates of poverty, crime, and
pollution, and less economic
opportunity.87 Combined, these
discriminatory practices have large
economic consequences. A 2020 study
estimates that if racial gaps in wages,
housing, access to higher education, and
lending were closed, the U.S. would
experience a $5 trillion dollar increase
in gross domestic product (GDP) from
2020 to 2025.88
Undue Prejudice and Economic
Inefficiency
Prejudicial discrimination has been
theorized and observed to be an
artificial barrier to market activities, and
as such, it can create a market
distortion.89 A variety of pathways for
agricultural market distortions due to
discrimination are possible. For
example, if prices paid for otherwise
identical cattle differed because of the
race, ethnicity, or other producer
characteristics that do not have any
bearing on productivity, rather than the
on the value of the marginal product of
the cattle, then the prejudice based on
these characteristics distorts prices and
in turn both output and investment.
While the specifics of producer returns
in contract production are different from
marketed production, producers
receiving a lower contract payment rate
or other unfavorable contract terms
simply because of the producers’ race or
other personal characteristics would
likewise induce market distortions.
papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_
id=4096092; Ken S. Cavalluzzo, Linda C.
Cavalluzzo, and John D. Wolken, ‘‘Competition,
Small Business Financing, and Discrimination:
Evidence from a New Survey,’’ The Journal of
Business, October 2022, available at https://
www.jstor.org/stable/pdf/10.1086/
341638.pdf?refreqid=excelsior%3Ab05443d9
a80629ef03bbe4cb6e7747e4&ab_
segments=&origin=&acceptTC=1.
87 Christensen, Peter, and Christopher Timmins.
‘‘Sorting or steering: The effects of housing
discrimination on neighborhood choice.’’ Journal of
Political Economy 130, no. 8 (2022): 2110–2163.
88 Closing the Racial Wealth Gap: The Economic
Costs of Black Inequality in the United States. Citi
GPS: Global Perspectives and Solutions. 2020.
Available at https://ir.citi.com/NvIUklHPil
z14Hwd3oxqZBLMn1_XPqo5FrxsZD0x6hhil8
4ZxaxEuJUWmak51UHvYk75VKeHCMI%3D.
89 Stiglitz, J. ‘‘Approaches to the Economics of
Discrimination’’, American Economic Review, vol.
63/2, May 1973: 287–295.
PO 00000
Frm 00012
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
Prejudicial discrimination can take
other forms besides wage, contract, or
price differentials, such as exclusionary
practices in product purchases or sales,
or higher lending costs. These examples
of artificial barriers preventing resources
from moving to their highest and best
uses via allocative efficiency, such that
marginal benefits equal marginal costs,
lead to market inefficiency. Lowering
the level of this market distortion would
increase market efficiency, albeit noting
there is limited information to
empirically assess the impacts of
discrimination on efficiency in
agricultural markets.
Undue Prejudice and Potential Market
Abuse in Concentrated Livestock
Markets
Like in other parts of the economy
and in other types of markets, those
participating in agricultural markets
from groups that have and continue to
suffer racial, ethnic, gender, and
religious prejudices may be particularly
vulnerable to market abuses, especially
in concentrated markets such as in the
livestock sector. This is because they
currently represent not only a very
small share of producers in the industry,
including those in the livestock sector
and among producers who have
production contracts, but their size,
sales, and incomes are lower than other
producers, leaving them more
economically isolated and with fewer
economic resources to counteract
concentrated market forces and actors.
In the livestock sector, the results of
historical prejudice and the risk of
present-day prejudice are apparent
when looking at data from the 2017
Census of Agriculture, which show that
currently a very small fraction of
livestock farms with production
contracts are operated by Black, Asian,
American Indian, or Native Hawaiian
producers (Figure 1). As described
earlier in this section, discriminatory
acts, especially against Black producers,
undoubtedly contributed to the current
low levels of racial and ethnic minority
participation in the livestock sector,
including among producers with
production contracts. These remaining
producers may be particularly
vulnerable to market abuses in
concentrated livestock markets.
E:\FR\FM\03OCP3.SGM
03OCP3
Federal Register / Vol. 87, No. 190 / Monday, October 3, 2022 / Proposed Rules
60021
Figure 1. Number of livestock and poultry farms with production contracts by race
and ethnicity of their producers
35,000
...,
V,
u
;
30,000
C:
0
u
6
.:;
25,000
u
::,
"'C
e 20,000
C.
....
..c:
·3
15,000
V)
...
....
E
~ 10,000
....0
(I)
E
s,ooo
::,
z
American
Indian
Asian
Black
Native
Hawaiian
Hispanic
White
Data source: 2017 Agricultural Census, National Agricultural Statistics Service,
Disparities in farm size and income
across racial and ethnic groups also
exist among livestock and poultry farms
with production contracts, highlighting
additional vulnerability for particular
groups in the sector. Figure 2 shows the
percentage and number of livestock and
poultry farms with production contracts
by the reported race or ethnicity of their
producers, categorized by level of Gross
Cash Farm Income (GCFI), which
includes commodity cash receipts, farmrelated income, and Government
payments.90 USDA’s Economic
Research Service (ERS) classifies small
farms as having a GCFI less than
$150,000 and up to $349,999 per year,
mid-sized farms as having GCFI
between $350,000 and $999,999, and
large-scale farms as having a GCFI equal
to or greater than $1,000,000. Farms are
also classified as being non-family
farms, which are farms in which an
operator or persons related to the
operator do not own a majority of the
business.91 These data indicate that
contracted livestock and poultry farms
with producers who identify as Black
and Native Hawaiian are more likely to
be in the lower income GCFI categories
than their white counterparts. To a
lesser extent, farms with producers
identifying as Native American also
tend to be in the lower income GCFI
categories than their White
counterparts’ farms. Markets dominated
by one or a few large packers or live
poultry dealers may be less accessible to
these smaller farms, which have limited
financial or other economic resources
with which to engage. They may also be
more vulnerable to discriminatory acts
or market abuses such as retaliation.
90 U.S. Department of Agriculture, Economic
Research Service, ‘‘Most farms are small, but largescale farms account for almost half of production,’’
available at: https://www.ers.usda.gov/data-
products/chart-gallery/gallery/chart-detail/
?chartId=58288 (last accessed Aug, 2022).
91 U.S. Department of Agriculture, Economic
Research Service, ‘‘Farm Structure and
Contracting,’’ available at: https://
www.ers.usda.gov/topics/farm-economy/farmstructure-and-organization/farm-structure-andcontracting/ (last accessed Aug. 2022).
VerDate Sep<11>2014
20:25 Sep 30, 2022
Jkt 259001
PO 00000
Frm 00013
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
E:\FR\FM\03OCP3.SGM
03OCP3
EP03OC22.069
lotter on DSK11XQN23PROD with PROPOSALS3
USDA.
60022
Federal Register / Vol. 87, No. 190 / Monday, October 3, 2022 / Proposed Rules
Figure 2. Percentage and number of livestock and poultry farms with production
contracts by GCFI and family farm status and by race and ethnicity of their
producers.
100%
90%
80%
70%
60%
50%
40%
30%
20%
10%
0%
American Indian
11\11
GCFI
Asian
< $150,000
GCFI >= $1,000,000
Black
Native Hawaiian
Hispanic
White
lllll GCFI $150,000 - $349,999 11 GCFI $350,000 - $999,999
Non-family farms
Notes: Number of farms displayed on bars in white text. Percentages reported by the bar
height on the vertical axis.
Data source: 2017 Agricultural Census, National Agricultural Statistics Service, USDA
In determining the proposed bases for
protection under this section, AMS
looked to several sources, including the
Statement of General Policy Under the
Packers and Stockyards Act published
by the Secretary of Agriculture in 1968
(Statement of General Policy) (9 CFR
203.12(f)), the regulations governing
USDA-conducted programs, and a series
of statutes identifying producers that
Congress has determined face special
disadvantages, are underserved, or are
otherwise more vulnerable to
prejudices.
The Statement of General Policy
reflects the current USDA policy on the
enforcement of the P&S Act. The
Statement of General Policy provides in
part that it’s a violation of sections 304,
307, and 312(a) of the Packers and
Stockyards Act for a stockyard owner or
market agency to discriminate, in the
furnishing of stockyard services or
facilities or in establishing rules or
regulations at the stockyard, because of
race, religion, color, or national origin of
VerDate Sep<11>2014
20:25 Sep 30, 2022
Jkt 259001
those persons using the stockyard
services or facilities. Such services and
facilities include, but are not limited to,
the restaurant, restrooms, drinking
fountains, lounge accommodations,
those furnished for the selling,
weighing, or other handling of the
livestock, and facilities for observing
such services.
While this part of the Statement of
General Policy applies to violations of
secs. 304, 307, and 312(a) of the Act—
related to the provision of services and
facilities at stockyards on an
unreasonable and discriminatory basis,
almost identical prohibitive language is
used in sec. 202 of the Act. Section 202
pertains to packers, swine contractors,
and live poultry dealers. Section 202(a)
of the Act prohibits any unjustly
discriminatory practice or device with
respect to livestock, meats, meat food
products or livestock products in
manufactured form, or live poultry.
AMS also considered USDA’s general
regulatory prohibition against
discrimination in USDA programs,
which governs how USDA provides
PO 00000
Frm 00014
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
services to producers and growers. Most
recently updated in 2014, it offers a
more current interpretation of antidiscrimination standards. The relevant
provision provides that no agency,
officer, or employee of the USDA shall,
on the grounds of race, color, national
origin, religion, sex, sexual orientation,
disability, age, marital status, family/
parental status, income derived from a
public assistance program, political
beliefs, or gender identity, exclude from
participation in, deny the benefits of, or
subject to discrimination any person in
the United States under any program or
activity conducted by the USDA.92
In that rulemaking, USDA identified
areas where discrimination against a
producer is an unacceptable denial of
access to USDA’s services.
92 7 CFR 15d.3; U.S. Department of Agriculture,
‘‘Nondiscrimination in Programs or Activities
Conducted by the United States Department of
Agriculture,’’ 79 FR 41406, July 16, 2014, available
at https://www.federalregister.gov/documents/2014/
07/16/2014-16325/nondiscrimination-in-programsor-activities-conducted-by-the-united-statesdepartment-of-agriculture (last accessed 8/9/2022).
E:\FR\FM\03OCP3.SGM
03OCP3
EP03OC22.070
lotter on DSK11XQN23PROD with PROPOSALS3
iii. Specific Proposed Bases
lotter on DSK11XQN23PROD with PROPOSALS3
Federal Register / Vol. 87, No. 190 / Monday, October 3, 2022 / Proposed Rules
AMS also looked to the legislative
mandates that emerged over the last
thirty years, directing USDA to make
extra efforts to overcome the barriers
that prevent members of those groups
from accessing USDA’s services and
agricultural markets generally.93
Congress adopted numerous statutes
seeking to remedy market access
barriers on the basis of prejudices across
a wide range of areas, including: 7
U.S.C. 8711 (base acres); 7 U.S.C. 2003
(target participation rates); 7 U.S.C. 7333
(Administration and operation of
noninsured crop assistance program); 7
U.S.C. 1932 (Assistance for rural
entities); 16 U.S.C. 2202a, 3801, 3835,
3839aa–2, 3841, and 3844
(conservation); 7 U.S.C. 8111 (Biomass
Crop Assistance Program); 7 U.S.C. 1508
(Federal crop insurance, covering
underserved producers defined as new,
beginning, and socially disadvantaged
farmers or ranchers and including
members of an Indian tribe); and 16
U.S.C. 3871e(d) (conservation, covering
historically underserved producers
defined as beginning, veteran, socially
disadvantaged, and limited-resource
farmers and ranchers). In 25 U.S.C.
4301(a) and elsewhere, Congress has
clearly expressed its intent for the
United States government to encourage
and foster tribal commerce and
economic development.94
The definitions and coverage in these
statutes varies to some extent. Some
focus principally on members of groups
that have experienced racial or ethnic
prejudices, while others include gender
prejudices. Additionally, some provide
further assistance to new and beginning
farmers and military service veterans
who are farmers. In sum, these statutes
reflect the now multi-decade priority of
U.S. agricultural policy to overcome
barriers that stand in the way of full
market access for all producers and
growers, with significant emphasis
placed on overcoming certain persistent
forms of racial, ethnic, and gender
prejudices that obstruct full market
access for some producers.
In interpreting the P&S Act, AMS has
sought to propose a rule that would
remove barriers to market access for
producers and growers most vulnerable
to being denied access. For the purposes
of this proposed rule, AMS is proposing
a prohibition on undue prejudice on the
basis of a covered producer’s
membership in a vulnerable group. We
93 For background, see Congressional Research
Service, Defining a Socially Disadvantaged Farmer
or Rancher (SDFR): In Brief (March 19, 2021),
available at https://crsreports.congress.gov/product/
pdf/R/R46727/6.
94 See, e.g., Native American Business
Development Act, 25 U.S.C. 4301(a).
VerDate Sep<11>2014
20:25 Sep 30, 2022
Jkt 259001
seek comment on whether to adopt one
of several options for the term ‘‘market
vulnerable individual,’’ and if so, which
one we should adopt. We are also
seeking comment on whether to
specifically delineate certain protected
classes.
Because of the Act’s broad application
discussed in an earlier section, ‘‘II.B.i.,
Authority provided by the Act,’’ the
similar language used in secs. 202, 304,
305, and 312 of the Act, and the series
of statutes outlining a range of
prejudices identified as being deserving
of public policy efforts to ensure full
market access, AMS finds it reasonable
that members of groups who have been
subjected to discrimination, prejudice,
disadvantage, or exclusion on the basis
of race, ethnicity, or gender should be
considered vulnerable and covered by
the prohibitions against undue
prejudice or disadvantage and unjust
discrimination as enumerated by sec.
202 of the Act.
AMS is proposing, and seeking
comment on, whether a flexible
definition of vulnerable group would be
advantageous to ensuring inclusive
market access for covered producers by
permitting an evolving as well as
market-specific application of the
regulation. Such an approach could
address barriers to inclusion as they
may arise. At the same time, AMS is
seeking comment on how to ensure that
most persons that would be protected
under the Statement of General Policy
and under USDA’s general regulations
prohibiting discrimination, as noted
above, could be protected under this
regulation.95 In particular, as noted
above AMS seeks comment on whether
to delineate certain specific groups as
examples of market vulnerable groups,
and also seeks comment on whether it
is preferable instead to prohibit
discrimination based on protected
classes, such as on the basis of race,
color, national origin, religion, sex,
sexual orientation, gender identity, age,
disability, marital status, and family
status. AMS seeks additional comment
on the appropriate approach to protect
market access for and stop unjust
discrimination against Indian tribes and
tribal members.
Refusing to deal, providing less
compensation, or any other type of
discrimination because of a person’s
particular non-economic characteristics
is the type of behavior both the Act and
USDA aim to prevent.
95 See, e.g., Pregnancy Discrimination Act, see
also Bostock v. Clayton Cnty., Georgia, 140 S. Ct.
at 1741.
PO 00000
Frm 00015
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
60023
C. Cooperatives—Proposed
§ 201.304(a)(1)
Proposed § 201.304(a)(1) also specifies
that regulated entities, which include
packers, swine contractors, or live
poultry dealers, may not discriminate
against a cooperative of covered
producers—i.e., covered producers who
collectively work together. For example,
individual covered producers may form
a cooperative to meet volume or other
contractual requirements when they
may not be able to meet those
requirements by themselves. A covered
producer is defined in the proposed
regulations at § 201.302 as a livestock
producer as defined in this section or
swine production contract grower or
poultry grower as defined in section 2(a)
of the Act. Covered producers acting as
a cooperative are an association or
group made up of one or more
producers collectively processing,
preparing for market, handling, and
marketing livestock or poultry. The P&S
Act includes cooperative associations in
the definition of ‘‘person’’ at 7 U.S.C.
182(1), providing that when used in the
Act ‘‘[t]he term ‘‘person’’ includes
individuals, partnerships, corporations,
and associations. . .’’
Covered producer cooperatives
improve economic conditions for
individual producers. They have been
demonstrated to be competitive and
responsive to meeting the needs of
regulated entities and the market.96 For
example, smaller livestock producers
may move towards cooperative
agreements on a regional basis to meet
buyers’ volume requirements.
Producers have indicated to AMS that
they feel such a move is necessary,
owing to the rise of concentration in the
markets and the decline in options for
smaller producers. Small cattle
producers have expressed their
concerns to AMS about disparate
treatment by packers between large and
small producers. Large packers have
commonly shown limited interest in
dealing with producers that operate on
a smaller capacity. On this point,
producers have informed AMS that
packers are in search of deals with large
quantities of product, and if a producer
is unable to meet demand for readily
available bulk quantities, that producer
is unable to compete in the industry.
96 At least some of the drafters of the Act fully
expected the Act to be consonant to the goals of
cooperatives: ‘‘My own conviction is that the
cooperative effort of producers and consumers to
get closer together in an effort to reduce the spread
between them is the most favorable tendency of our
time, so far as the question of marketing and
distribution is concerned.’’ 61 Cong. Rec. 1882
(1921).
E:\FR\FM\03OCP3.SGM
03OCP3
60024
Federal Register / Vol. 87, No. 190 / Monday, October 3, 2022 / Proposed Rules
lotter on DSK11XQN23PROD with PROPOSALS3
Producers testified in 2010 about
packer buyers pulling out of their smallscale feedlots for months in retaliation
for producers seeking higher prices and
not allotting their entire herd capacity.
Packer buyers often prefer to include
large quantities on single transactions to
lower transactions costs and maximize
profits.97 Adding protections for smaller
producers that wish to work together to
form cooperatives would enable smaller
producers to (1) form cooperatives
without fear of prejudice or
disadvantage, and (2) reduce
transactions costs for individual
member producers.
This proposed regulation is intended,
in part, to benefit smaller producers—
who lack the necessary land, capital, or
financing (or for other reasons may not
wish) to establish a large enough
operation to meet preferred contractual
requirements—by preventing
discrimination against their cooperative
operations. Through cooperation, one or
more producers may be able to jointly
meet the requirements and participate
as a producer in the industry, allowing
producers to operate more efficiently.
Preventing discrimination against
producer cooperatives will provide
another avenue for producers who
otherwise might not have been able to
participate in the market.
While this section proposes that
regulated entities may not prejudice or
disadvantage cooperatives of covered
producers, based on their protected
status as a cooperative under this
regulation, AMS notes that regulated
entities may decline contracting with
cooperatives for other justified
economic reasons—i.e., for reasons
other than the prospective business
partner’s status as a cooperative. For
example, a regulated entity may refuse
to contract with a cooperative of
covered producers when the contract
would not be cost-effective for the
entity, regardless of the cooperative
status of the producers. In this
hypothetical example, the regulated
entity would not be unduly prejudicing
cooperatives of covered producers based
on their status as a cooperative. Instead,
the regulated entity would have a
nonprejudicial basis for their business
decision. AMS notes that antitrust laws
also prohibit cooperatives themselves
from participating in certain
97 U.S. Department of Justice & U.S. Department
of Agriculture, Public Workshops, Exploring
Competition Issues in Agriculture Livestock
Workshop: A Dialogue on Competition Issues
Facing Farmers in Today’s Agricultural
Marketplaces, Fort Collins, Colorado, August 27,
2010. Available at https://www.justice.gov/sites/
default/files/atr/legacy/2012/08/20/coloradoagworkshop-transcript.pdf.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
20:25 Sep 30, 2022
Jkt 259001
anticompetitive behavior. As discussed
earlier, undue prejudice and
disadvantage may inhibit producers’
ability to obtain fair market value for
their livestock and poultry and would
be prohibited under proposed
§ 201.304(a)(1). Proposed § 201.304(a)(1)
aims to encourage a diverse agricultural
market and prevent undue prejudice
and disadvantage and unjust
discrimination against cooperatives.
Congress has long protected
cooperatives in the agricultural space,
acknowledging the need for farmers to
meet the economic demands of the
market. One year after the passage of the
P&S Act, Congress passed the CapperVolstead Act (Pub. L. 67–146), which
permits producer cooperatives to
collectively process, prepare for market,
handle, and market their products. In a
decision related to an antitrust action
against a nonprofit cooperative
association whose members were
involved in production and marketing
of broiler chickens, the Supreme Court
noted that farmers faced special
challenges in the agricultural market
and therefore cooperatives are afforded
legal protections in helping them
address those challenges.98 Congress
also passed the Agricultural Fair
Practices Act,99 which provides
enhanced protections to those seeking to
form a cooperative. In particular, that
statute prevents handlers from
performing certain types of pricing and
contract discrimination, coercion, and
other practices that undermine
cooperatives.
This proposed rule would provide
additional protection for cooperatives
by preventing a regulated entity from
isolating cooperatives through contract
termination and preventing cooperatives
98 Nat’l Broiler Mktg. Ass’n v. United States, 436
U.S. 816, 825–26, 98 S. Ct. 2122, 2129, 56 L. Ed.
2d 728 (1978) (‘‘Farmers were perceived to be in a
particularly harsh economic position. They were
subject to the vagaries of market conditions that
plague agriculture generally, and they had no
means individually of responding to those
conditions. Often the farmer had little choice about
who his buyer would be and when he would sell.
A large portion of an entire year’s labor devoted to
the production of a crop could be lost if the farmer
were forced to bring his harvest to market at an
unfavorable time. Few farmers, however, so long as
they could act only individually, had sufficient
economic power to wait out an unfavorable
situation. Farmers were seen as being caught in the
hands of processors and distributors who, because
of their position in the market and their relative
economic strength, were able to take from the
farmer a good share of whatever profits might be
available from agricultural production. By allowing
farmers to join together in cooperatives, Congress
hoped to bolster their market strength and to
improve their ability to weather adverse economic
periods and to deal with processors and
distributors.’’).
99 Public Law 90–288, Apr. 16, 1968, 82 Stat. 93
(7 U.S.C. 2301 et seq.).
PO 00000
Frm 00016
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
from accessing markets for their
products. As noted above, the P&S Act
intended to improve the agricultural
market and includes associations in the
definition of ‘‘person’’ when referred to
in the Act. The Act affords cooperative
associations the same protections
against discrimination as are afforded to
all other covered producers. 7 U.S.C.
182(1). Thus, protections for
cooperatives against discrimination
were contemplated at the time of the
Act’s passage.100
D. Enumerated Prejudices
Proposed § 201.302(a)(2) outlines an
inexhaustive list of prejudices that, if
based upon the covered producer’s
status, the regulation prohibits. The
harm that may be done through
discriminatory actions cannot be neatly
cataloged, but the proposed
§ 201.302(a)(2) sets forth injuries that
the agency believes are inherently
prejudicial: offering less favorable
terms, refusing to deal, differential
contract enforcement, and contract
termination or non-renewal. Under
proposed § 201.302(b), prejudicial
actions are to be considered together
with the covered producer’s
membership in a market vulnerable
group or cooperative, and they would
not by themselves be violations. AMS
seeks comment on the scope of these
acts.
E. Retaliation
i. Retaliation as Discrimination Under
the Act
Proposed § 201.304(b) would establish
protected activities for covered
producers and would prohibit regulated
entities from retaliatory conduct on the
basis of those activities. Regulated
entities wield significant economic
power given their vertical relationships
with producers. Regulated entities
choosing to discriminate among
producers using their market power
advantages for the purpose of
preventing certain producers, or groups
of producers, from engaging in the
behaviors and activities discussed
below, is disparate treatment that is
unjustly discriminatory. This type of
discrimination is oftentimes exercised
through retaliation. The method of
retaliation may take many forms.
Accordingly, the proposed rule is
designed to prohibit a variety of adverse
actions. However, the proposed
regulations are also narrowly tailored,
requiring the adverse action to be linked
to specific protected activities. Adverse
actions not tied to the activities
100 H.Rep.
E:\FR\FM\03OCP3.SGM
No. 85–1048, 1957.
03OCP3
60025
Federal Register / Vol. 87, No. 190 / Monday, October 3, 2022 / Proposed Rules
proposed would not be regulated under
this proposal.
ii. Economic Rationale
While the statute does not require
market-wide harm as a condition to
forbid retaliation, which is an abuse that
undermines market integrity, this
section explains the adverse economic
effects of retaliation, which include
harm across the marketplace. Indeed,
oligopsonistic or monopsonistic market
structures can allow firms with large
market shares to use their market power
advantage to punish certain producer
behaviors that the firm believes could
offset their market power advantage or
even to punish producer behaviors that
are unrelated to the product or service
they provide. When firms retaliate by
canceling contracts, selectively
enforcing contract terms, renewing
contracts with unfavorable terms for the
producer, or otherwise impairing
producers’ ability to remain
economically competitive as a penalty
for their engagement in the activities
identified in the next section, that
conduct likely results in economic
inefficiencies and should be prohibited
on a market wide basis, even if the
specific retaliatory act only affects one
individual. Such impacts are especially
difficult to address when those firms
maintain dominant positions in the
markets.
Retaliation against even one seller
could presumably have a market-wide
chilling effect on others (at least within
the area where the retaliating entity is
dominant). However, the ability to use
such a tool does require the right
conditions, such as those that exist in
concentrated livestock markets where,
in many cases, few or one firm hold a
dominate position. It is unlikely that
packers or poultry dealers operating in
highly competitive markets (in which
they are not in a dominant economic
position) could effectively use
retaliation, since livestock producers
could simply find other buyers with
whom to do business.
Economic measures of firm
concentration may help to identify
when retaliation may be more easily
employed in a market, albeit noting that
an empirical relationship between
retaliation and concentration measures
in livestock markets has not been
established.
The following table shows the level of
concentration in the livestock and
poultry slaughtering industries for
2010–2020 using four-firm
Concentration Ratios (CR4).
TABLE 2—FOUR-FIRM CONCENTRATION RATIO IN LIVESTOCK AND POULTRY SLAUGHTER 101
Steers &
heifers
(%)
Year
lotter on DSK11XQN23PROD with PROPOSALS3
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
2017
2018
2019
2020
.................................................................................................................
.................................................................................................................
.................................................................................................................
.................................................................................................................
.................................................................................................................
.................................................................................................................
.................................................................................................................
.................................................................................................................
.................................................................................................................
.................................................................................................................
.................................................................................................................
Hogs
(%)
85
85
85
85
83
85
84
83
84
85
81
Broilers
(%)
65
64
64
64
62
66
66
66
70
67
64
Turkeys
(%)
51
52
51
54
51
51
50
51
54
53
53
56
55
53
53
58
57
57
53
55
55
55
The table shows the combined market
share of the four largest steer and heifer
slaughterers remained stable between 83
and 85 percent from 2010 to 2019 and
dropped to 81 percent in 2020. Fourfirm concentration ratios for hog and
broiler slaughter has also remained
relatively stable between 62 and 70
percent and 51 and 54 percent,
respectively. The data above are
estimates of national four-firm
concentration ratios at the national
level, but the relevant economic markets
for livestock and poultry may be
regional or local, and concentration in
the relevant market may be higher than
the national level.
As discussed previously, regional
concentration is often higher than
national concentration for hogs.102
Based on AMS’s experience conducting
investigations and monitoring cattle
markets, there are commonly only one
or two buyers in some local geographic
markets, and few sellers have the option
of selling fed cattle to more than three
or four packers.
Though poultry markets may appear
to be the least concentrated in terms of
their national four-firm concentration
ratios, relevant economic markets for
poultry growing services are more
localized than markets for fed cattle or
hogs, and local concentration in poultry
markets is often greater than in hog and
other livestock markets. The following
table highlights this issue by showing
the limited ability a poultry grower has
to switch to a different integrator using
the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index
(HHI).103 Similar to a CR4, HHI is an
indicator of market concentration, with
the index being increasing as market
shares across firms (packers) become
more unequal and/or the number of
these firms decrease. Markets with HHIs
above 2,500 are in some cases
considered highly concentrated. The
following table is a modification of a
table in MacDonald (2104), adding HHI
indices to the latter’s calculations of the
integrators in the broiler grower’s
geographic region. The HHIs in the table
assume equal market share for each
integrator, and as such are the minimum
HHIs possible (at least with 2 to 4
growers). They show that 88.4%
(72.2%) of growers are facing an
integrator HHI of at least 2,500 (3,333).
The data suggests that the majority of
contract broiler growers in the U.S. are
in markets where the sellers have the
potential for market power advantage.
101 U.S. Department of Agriculture, AMS Packers
and Stockyards annual reports. Available at https://
www.ams.usda.gov/reports/psd-annual-reports (last
accessed 8/9/2022).
102 Wise, T. A., S. E. Trist. ‘‘Buyer Power in U.S.
Hog Markets: A Critical Review of the Literature,’’
Tufts University, Global Development and
Environment Institute (GDAE) Working Paper No.
10–04, August 2010, available at: https://sites.tufts.
edu/gdae/files/2020/03/1004HogBuyerPower.pdf.TAbl (last accessed 8/9/
2022).
103 MacDonald, James M., and Nigel Key. ‘‘Market
power in poultry production contracting? Evidence
from a farm survey.’’ Journal of Agricultural and
Applied Economics 44, no. 4 (2012): 477–490.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
20:25 Sep 30, 2022
Jkt 259001
PO 00000
Frm 00017
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
E:\FR\FM\03OCP3.SGM
03OCP3
60026
Federal Register / Vol. 87, No. 190 / Monday, October 3, 2022 / Proposed Rules
TABLE 3—INTEGRATORS IN THE BROILER GROWERS’ REGION AND ASSOCIATED MARKET POWER INDICES
Minimum HHI
of integrators
in grower’s
area
Integrators in grower’s area
Farms
Birds
Number
Percent of total
lotter on DSK11XQN23PROD with PROPOSALS3
1 .................................................................................
2 .................................................................................
3 .................................................................................
4 .................................................................................
>4 ...............................................................................
No Response .............................................................
Retaliation by oligopolistic or
monopolistic firms can be effectuated in
the pursuit of economic self-interest or
be done against such interest for some
nonpecuniary reason.104 In the case of
economic self-interest, oligopsonistic or
monopsonistic integrators or packers
may use retaliation to facilitate their
ability to earn excess rents. However,
this use of retaliation, as a means to
protect excess profits, is only possible
when markets for livestock are
characterized by few integrators or
packers. Where producers have few, if
any, alternative packers, or integrators
to engage with, the act of not renewing
a contract, as retaliation for unfavorable
behavior or actions, can cause economic
inefficiencies.
Retaliation may also be used by
integrators and packers to ensure that
regulators or new entrants cannot
discipline their behavior in the
marketplace. Both regulators and new
entrants may be inhibited by the
inability to communicate with market
participants. Regulators may be unable
to obtain the information needed to
learn of or establish violations, while
prospective new entrants may be unable
to establish necessary market
relationships with industry participants.
Many producers have expressed
concerns about retaliatory behavior from
regulated entities with respect to
activities inextricably relevant to the
livestock and poultry markets. Examples
include contract poultry and hog
producers afraid to talk with USDA
representatives, file comments with
USDA (or not file comments that adopt
their integrator’s view), seek
enforcement of contracts, organize
associations, or even attend association
meetings, opt out of arbitration,
complain about feed outages and
company personnel behavior, and
question the need for farm upgrades.105
104 Fehr, Ernst, and Simon Ga
¨ chter. ‘‘Fairness and
retaliation: The economics of reciprocity.’’ Journal
of economic perspectives 14, no. 3 (2000): 159–181.
105 U.S. Department of Justice & U.S. Department
of Agriculture, Public Workshops Exploring
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:08 Sep 30, 2022
Production
Jkt 259001
10,000
5,000
3,333
2,500
........................
........................
21.7
30.2
20.4
16.1
7.8
3.8
In cattle and independent hog
production, private complaints to AMS
include fear that packers will refuse to
visit farms or feedlots, offer bids on
livestock, purchase livestock from
disfavored producers, and other more
subtle behaviors, like delaying delivery
or shipment and manipulating where
producers fall in order of procurement.
In addition, it is also possible that
discriminatory or retaliatory acts by
packers or integrators intended to
prevent the transfer of rents also
negatively affect efficiency by reducing
the incentives for investment, beneficial
coordination of actions, or adoption of
innovative production process. In one
case, a court found that an integrator
retaliated against a grower who was a
leader of a growers’ association,106
suggesting both that producer
coordination may reduce the packers’/
integrators’ oligopsony excess profit and
that growers’ ability to compete in these
markets may be harmed by retaliation.
In another court case, James v. Tyson
Foods, Inc., fifty-four poultry growers
sued the integrator for retaliatory
actions and were awarded $10 million
in damages as a result.107
F. Prohibition on Retaliation—Proposed
§ 201.304(b)
To address the dangers of the
retaliatory practices described above,
AMS is proposing to add § 201.304(b) to
the regulations. Proposed
§ 201.304(b)(1) would prohibit and
provide examples of retaliatory
practices by regulated entities against
covered producers who engage in
protected activities. Proposed
§ 201.304(b)(2)(i) through (vi) lists these
protected activities.
Competition in Agriculture, Poultry Workshop, May
21, 2010, Alabama A&M University Normal,
Alabama. Available at Poultry Workshop Transcript
(justice.gov).
106 Terry v. Tyson Farms, Inc., 604 F.3d 272 (6th
Cir. 2010).
107 James v. Tyson Foods, Inc., 292 P.3d 10 (Okla.,
2012).
PO 00000
Frm 00018
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
Can change to
another integrator
Percent of farms
23.4
31.9
20.4
14.9
6.7
2.7
24.5
31.7
19.7
14.8
6.6
2.7
7
52
62
71
77
NA
Under § 201.304(b)(1), regulated
entities would be prohibited from
retaliating or otherwise taking an
adverse action against a covered
producer because the covered producer
participated in the activities described
in § 201.304(b), to the extent that these
activities are not otherwise prohibited
by Federal or state antitrust laws. While
a group of producers might be protected
from retaliation when associating in the
production or marketing of livestock,
producers would not be protected from
the adverse action of packers if the
producers engaged in a violation of
Federal or state antitrust law. AMS
expects that prohibited retaliation
would include, but not be limited to
termination of contracts, non-renewal of
contracts, refusing to deal with a
covered producer, and interference in
farm real estate transactions or contracts
with third parties. The proposed rule is
designed to prohibit all such actions
with an adverse impact on a covered
producer.
AMS has chosen these specific
examples of retaliation because they
represent the retaliatory practices that
have been the most common causes for
complaints or because AMS has
otherwise determined them to be
recurring problems in the livestock and
poultry industries. Covered producers
have experienced termination or nonrenewal of their contracts for numerous
reasons. Covered producers who have
not personally experienced these forms
of retaliation have nevertheless
expressed fear of such retaliation
through direct communication with
AMS personnel, at workshops, and in
comments on previous related
rulemakings. Related to termination and
non-renewal of contracts is a regulated
entity’s refusal to deal. This proposed
rule extends protections against
retaliation to covered producers who are
refused a new contract due to their
involvement in protected activities. A
regulated entity would also be
prohibited from interfering in a covered
producer’s farm real estate transactions
E:\FR\FM\03OCP3.SGM
03OCP3
Federal Register / Vol. 87, No. 190 / Monday, October 3, 2022 / Proposed Rules
or contracts with third parties. Impeding
or obstructing a covered producer’s
attempts to sell his or her farm or ability
to contract with a third party as a result
of his or her participation in certain
activities hinders a covered producer’s
ability to freely participate in the
market. AMS believes that punishing
covered producers or denying them
opportunities afforded to other covered
producers because they engaged in
certain activities is an unjustly
discriminatory practice. Not only do
retaliatory practices harm individual
covered producers; recurrent instances
and patterns of retaliation erode market
integrity and discourage fairness and
competition in the livestock and poultry
markets.
The specific examples of retaliatory
practices listed in the proposed
regulation are not meant to be
exhaustive; other retaliatory actions
with an adverse impact on covered
producers would be prohibited as well.
When investigating complaints of
retaliatory practices that do not conform
to one of these examples, AMS would,
as it has in the past, continue to use its
expertise to determine whether a
regulated entity’s action has an adverse
impact on the covered producer.
lotter on DSK11XQN23PROD with PROPOSALS3
G. Bases for Protected Activities—
Proposed § 201.304(b)
AMS has identified three categories of
producer activities that we propose to
be protected due to concerns about
retaliatory behavior from packers, live
poultry dealers, and swine contractors.
Starting with the recognition that these
activities are related to the business of
being a producer or grower or
involvement in that sectoral or
geographic community, the criteria used
to establish the three categories—
consistent with the Act’s purpose to
safeguard farmers and ranchers against
receiving less than the true market value
of their livestock 108—include the extent
to which the activities are supported
under existing legal doctrine and the
activities’ potential to mitigate market
power abuses or enhance economic
efficiency. The following sections
discuss three categories of protected
activities: (i) assertion of rights, (ii)
associational participation, and (iii)
lawful communication, in the context of
the criteria.
i. Assertion of Rights
The basis of rights in this context is
two-fold, including both legal rights
derived under various statutes and
contractual rights contained in
agreements with regulated entities.
108 Stafford
v. Wallace, 258 U.S. 495 (1922).
VerDate Sep<11>2014
20:25 Sep 30, 2022
Jkt 259001
Assertions of rights may be necessary to
ensure that covered producers are
receiving appropriate treatment in their
dealings with regulated entities.
Disputes relating to contract terms and
legal compliance could be over
differences between the buyer and seller
over what constitutes mutually
agreeable returns or could even be over
issues extraneous to the actual product
or service provided by the covered
producer. Access to existing legal
remedies under state and Federal law
may be necessary for covered producers
to effectuate their bargained-for
exchange in contracting and to address
their inability to make complete
contracts and associated hold-up risk,
which leads to under investment and
less efficient market allocations. Holdup is the risk growers face at the time
of contract renewal when integrators
make contract renewal dependent on
further grower investments not
disclosed at the time of the original
agreements.109
Some regulated entities may prefer to
limit, minimize, or otherwise eliminate
producer assertions or legal and
contractual rights, as they are likely
associated with additional economic
costs. For example, a poultry grower
may seek to enforce a production
contract term providing the grower with
the right to five flocks annually, when
the grower only received four flocks. If
a regulated entity sought to punish a
grower seeking enforcement of this
term, the grower’s risk of contract
termination would likely outweigh the
benefit to them of contract enforcement,
and thereby undermine their contract,
from the grower’s perspective. On the
other hand, the regulated entity’s cost of
breaching or terminating the agreement
may be lower than their cost of
performance under the contract.
Systemic conduct of this type would be
an abuse of market power and result in
reduced allocative efficiency. Attempts
to limit, deter, or curtail producers’
assertions of rights mitigates or removes
a primary producer tool for proper
enforcement of their rights.
ii. Associational Participation
While individual producers and
growers operate at a tremendous
informational deficit compared to the
larger sophisticated packer operations,
producer and grower organizations and
associations can mitigate incomplete
and asymmetric information frictions in
the market. Producer and grower
109 Vukina, Tom, and Porametr Leegomonchai.
‘‘Oligopsony Power, Asset Specificity, and HoldUp: Evidence from the Broiler Industry.’’ American
Journal of Agricultural Economics 88 (2006).
PO 00000
Frm 00019
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
60027
organizations may provide individual
covered producers the opportunity to
counter other market power imbalances
that exist in the livestock and poultry
industries. Associational participation is
connected to the provision of the
product or service of growing poultry or
raising livestock and can serve to
improve producer productivity.
Agriculture associations and
organizations have historically been
favored under Federal 110 and state laws
and exempted from certain types of
Federal antitrust violations under the
Capper-Volstead Act.111 By narrowing
the asymmetrical information gap and
creating other benefits, associations can
enhance production and allocative
efficiencies.
Growers have expressed concern that
associations and organizations have
repeatedly been targets of retaliatory
behavior, and in some instances, USDA
and DOJ have intervened under the P&S
Act. In the 1960s, poultry growers in
Arkansas and Mississippi joined
organizations to try to advance their
interests and protections in their
contracts with poultry companies. The
poultry companies with which they had
contracts engaged in harassment,
threats, intimidation, and retaliation
against the associations and the growers
that joined them. A USDA
Administrative Law Judge held that the
poultry companies’ conduct was a
violation of the P&S Act and ordered the
companies to cease and desist from their
unlawful actions and reinstate the
growers who were retaliated against.112
In 1989, a company operating a
poultry slaughtering complex in
northern Florida, terminated its contract
with a poultry grower who was the
president of a poultry growers’
association. The U.S. District Court
issued an injunction against the
company, finding that it acted to
hamper legal action by the growers’
association and to discourage other
growers from presenting grievances to
110 See 7 U.S.C. 2301; 7 U.S.C. 291. The
Agriculture Fair Practices Act prevents agricultural
handlers from discrimination and coercion against
individuals who belong to cooperatives. Among
other things, this statute prohibits handlers from
undermining a cooperative’s ordinary operations by
either bribing members of the cooperative or
making false reports about the cooperative’s
operations.
111 For example, under Missouri’s Nonprofit
Cooperative Marketing Law, RSMo 1939 section
14362, a nonprofit cooperative is exempt from a
number of taxes (including sales tax), and only pay
an annual fee of ten dollars.
112 See In re: Arkansas Valley Industries, Inc.,
Ralston Purina Company, and Tyson’s Foods, Inc.,
27 Ag. Dec. 84 (January 23, 1968), and In Re: Curtis
Davis, Leon Davis, and Moody Davis d/b/a
Pelahatchie Poultry Company, 28 Ag. Dec. 406
(April 3, 1969).
E:\FR\FM\03OCP3.SGM
03OCP3
60028
Federal Register / Vol. 87, No. 190 / Monday, October 3, 2022 / Proposed Rules
governmental authorities. USDA and
DOJ filed a lawsuit,along with poultry
growers, to enjoin the company’s
actions as constituting an unfair,
unjustly discriminatory, and deceptive
practice and device, and an undue and
unreasonable prejudice and
disadvantage, in violation of the P&S
Act.113 The Court agreed and also
determined that the company’s actions
would constitute obstruction of justice,
extortion, mail fraud, and wire fraud in
furtherance of a pattern of racketeering
activity.
In these cases, courts determined that
attempts to limit, deter, or curtail
associational participation limits lawful
information exchanges and prevents or
dilutes the potential for covered
producers to engage in pro-competitive
collaboration. This proposed regulation
seeks to codify this line of analysis,
which has arisen under direct
enforcement of the statutory terms, and
in the face of more recent court
decisions involving private litigation, to
provide clarity to market participants
regarding USDA enforcement priorities
going forward.114
iii. Lawful Communications
Under this proposed rule, covered
producer communications would
include any lawful communications
with government agencies or other
persons for the purpose of improving
the production or marketing of livestock
or poultry, exploring a possible business
relationship, or supporting proceedings
under the Act against a regulated entity.
Broadly, these types of communication
improve transparency, facilitate
compliance with and enforcement of
relevant laws and regulations, and can
serve to mitigate market power abuse
and enhance production and allocative
efficiencies, as well as protect market
integrity.
lotter on DSK11XQN23PROD with PROPOSALS3
Communications With Government
Agencies and Communications Related
to Proceedings Under the Act
Related to ‘‘assertions of rights,’’
covered producers seeking the
enforcement of a regulatory scheme
designed to benefit them will likely
need to communicate with government
representatives. This communication is
only incidental to the product or service
provided to the regulated entity, and
113 Baldree
v. Cargill, Inc. and United States v.
Cargill, Inc., et al., 758 F.Supp.704 (M.D.Fla. 1990)
114 See, e.g., Terry v. Tyson Farms Inc. 604 F.3d
272, 275 (6th Cir. 2009). On these line of cases, see
also Michael Kades, ‘‘Protecting Livestock
Producers and Chicken Growers,’’ Washington
Center for Equitable Growth (May 5, 2022),
available at https://equitablegrowth.org/researchpaper/protecting-livestock-producers-and-chickengrowers/.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:24 Sep 30, 2022
Jkt 259001
communication with government
representatives serves numerous public
policy interests. Abuses of market
power to restrict communication related
to government compliance programs
would systematically result in
deprivation of legal rights, losses in
income or welfare for producers, and
costs to markets and society.115 Covered
producers have expressed concerns
regarding their communications with
government agencies and support for
government actions. For example: a
cattle producer believes he has been the
victim of weight fraud by a regulated
entity, but as a producer with limited
alternative outlets for sale of his cattle,
the producer may be hesitant to report
the fraud to USDA or other authorities
for fear the regulated entity will refuse
to engage in future business.
Communications for the Purpose of
Improving Production/Marketing or
Exploring a Business Relationship
As with communications related to
enforcement, communications for the
purpose of improving production or
marketing or exploring business
relationships aid covered producers in
obtaining fair market value for their
livestock and poultry. Protecting such
communications would protect the
producer’s ability to obtain help from
experts and professionals unaffiliated
with the regulated entity. In addition,
covered producers would be able to
explore business opportunities without
fear of reprisal from firms with which
they currently do business.
Communications of this type can
improve production efficiency and price
discovery mechanisms.
Retaliatory actions can also result
from a blend of protected activities. In
Philson v. Cold Creek Farms, Inc.,
turkey growers alleged in part that the
poultry company provided them with
lower quality poults than it provided to
other growers, and that the company’s
motivation for doing that was to punish
and discourage growers from voicing
their complaints (lawful
communication) about the company’s
practices. Some of the turkey growers
also alleged that their poultry contracts
were terminated in retaliation for their
objections to the poultry company’s
weighing and computing practices
115 Heese, Jonas, and Gerardo Pe
´ rez-Cavazos.
‘‘The effect of retaliation costs on employee
whistleblowing.’’ Journal of Accounting and
Economics 71, no. 2–3 (2021): 101385. European
Commission, Directorate-General for Internal
Market, Industry, Entrepreneurship and SMEs,
Rossi, L., McGuinn, J., Fernandes, M., Estimating
the economic benefits of whistleblower protection in
public procurement: final report, Publications
Office, 2017, https://data.europa.eu/doi/10.2873/
125033 (last accessed Aug. 2022).
PO 00000
Frm 00020
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
(assertion of rights). The Court noted
that ‘‘[s]uch a retaliatory act is properly
challenged under the PSA as it
adversely affects competition and could
be considered unfair, unjustly
discriminatory or deceptive.’’ 116 Here,
we see retaliation related to two
categories of protected activities.
H. Delineation of Protected Activities
Paragraphs (b)(2)(i) through (vi) of
proposed § 201.304 list activities that
would be protected. Regulated entities
would be prohibited from retaliating
against covered producers due to the
covered producer’s participation in
these protected activities. AMS has
determined that a covered producer’s
ability to freely participate in these
activities without fear of retaliation is
essential to promoting fair and
competitive markets in the livestock and
poultry industries. Many of these
activities also represent activities for
which covered producers have
experienced or expressed fear of
retaliation.
Specifically, proposed paragraph
(b)(2)(i) would protect a covered
producer’s ability to communicate with
a government agency regarding the
production of poultry or livestock, or to
petition for redress of grievances before
a court, legislature, or government
agency. A covered producer’s ability to
communicate with a government agency
is an essential tool for ensuring that a
covered producer’s rights are protected.
Likewise, a covered producer must be
able to freely petition for the redress of
grievances for the protections afforded
to covered producers by laws and
regulations to have their intended effect.
Proposed paragraph (b)(2)(ii) would
protect a covered producer’s ability to
assert any of the rights granted under
the Act or the regulations in 9 CFR part
201, or to assert rights afforded by their
contact. These rights include, for
example, growers’ rights to view the
weighing of flocks, which is legally
protected but which growers have
complained is not practically
enforceable. Although these rights are
ostensibly protected by laws,
regulations, or legal contracts, they lose
their efficacy if covered producers suffer
repercussions for asserting them.
Proposed paragraph (b)(2)(iii) would
protect a covered producer’s ability to
assert the right to formor joinaproducer
or grower association or organization, or
to collectively process, prepare for
market, handle, or market livestock or
poultry.An assertion of rights in this
context may involve expressing interest
116 Philson v. Cold Creek Farms, Inc., 947 F.
Supp. 197 at 202 (E.D.N.C. 1996).
E:\FR\FM\03OCP3.SGM
03OCP3
lotter on DSK11XQN23PROD with PROPOSALS3
Federal Register / Vol. 87, No. 190 / Monday, October 3, 2022 / Proposed Rules
or intent to engage in these activities or
engaging in these activities.
Associations and organizations provide
a means for covered producers to share
information regarding the production of
poultry and livestock, to potentially
uncover recurrent problematic practices
in the industry, and to potentially
organize to seek redress of grievances,
among other benefits. Collectively
processing, preparing for market,
handling, or marketing livestock or
poultry affords covered producers the
opportunity to combine their resources
to potentially counteract market
imbalances. AMS believes that
retaliating against producers for
engaging in these activities hinders the
free flow of information and hampers
producers’ ability to fairly compete in
the market.
Proposed paragraph (b)(2)(iv) would
protect a covered producer’s ability to
communicate or cooperate with a
person for the purposes of improving
production or marketing of livestock or
poultry. Such communication may
include, for example, communication
with extension programs or with
independent veterinarians and animal
health experts.
Proposed paragraph (b)(2)(v) would
protect a covered producer’s ability to
communicate or negotiate with a
regulated entity for the purposes of
exploring a business relationship. A
covered producer may want to seek
information from a regulated entity with
which they do not currently have a
business relationship regarding the
possibility of a future business
relationship, such as entering into a
contract. Protecting this activity would
allow covered producers to freely
compare potential business
relationships and choose between
several regulated entities, encouraging
competition.
Finally, proposed paragraph (b)(2)(vi)
would protect a covered producer’s
ability to support or participate as a
witness in any proceeding under the Act
or a proceeding that relates to an alleged
violation of law by a regulated entity.
Owing to the close-knit and
concentrated markets in which covered
producers operate, protecting some
covered producers as witnesses may
enable other covered producers to
effectuate their rights under the Act and
related laws. Without such protections,
enforcement of the Act may be
frustrated overall.
I. Recordkeeping
To help lessen these threats of
retaliation, the proposed rule contains
compliance systems for monitoring and
facilitating compliance and change
VerDate Sep<11>2014
20:25 Sep 30, 2022
Jkt 259001
within companies. Vital to such an
effort will be AMS’s ability to inspect
relevant records, as they may exist, such
as policies and procedures, staff training
and producer information materials,
data and testing, board of directors’
oversight materials, and other relevant
materials. AMS may utilize compliance
inspections, company reports to AMS,
and public analyses to benchmark
industry practice and improve market
standards. AMS believes that its
recordkeeping approach will enable it to
monitor and facilitate a regulated
entity’s approach to compliance at the
highest levels, including the tone at the
top: chief executive officers and boards
of directors. The tone and compliance
practices set by senior executives can be
expected to play a vital role in
establishing a corporate culture of
compliance, which is a critical defense
against legal and regulatory violations
and a first step towards more inclusive
market practices.
Proposed paragraph (c) would ensure
appropriate recordkeeping regarding
compliance. It indicates certain specific
records should be kept for a period of
5 years. Specifically, regulated entities
would be required to retain, to the
extent that they produce them, policies
and procedures, staff training materials,
materials informing covered producers
about reporting mechanisms and
protections, compliance testing, board
of directors’ oversight materials, and
records about the number and nature of
complaints received relevant to
prejudice and retaliation. AMS is
proposing 5 years to provide a broader
ability to monitor the evolution of
compliance practices over time in this
area, and to ensure that records are
available for what may be complex
evidentiary cases.
Recordkeeping, as described in the
proposed rule, is a commonly utilized
regulatory compliance and monitoring
mechanism among market regulators.117
Access to these records will assist AMS
in assessing the effectiveness of the
regulated entity’s compliance with
§ 201.304. Existing gaps in both
generally applicable agricultural and
PSD-specific data collection make
addressing widespread reports of
discriminatory behavior difficult.
Recordkeeping is critical if AMS is to
fulfill its duties to prevent and secure
enforcement against undue prejudice
117 See, e.g., generally, Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System, ‘‘Federal Trade
Commission Act, Section 5: Unfair or Deceptive
Acts or Practices,’’ Consumer Compliance
Handbook, available at https://
www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/supmanual/cch/
ftca.pdf (last accessed June 2022).
PO 00000
Frm 00021
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
60029
and unjust discrimination in the
relevant agricultural sector.
J. Request for Comments on Proposed
§ 201.304
AMS specifically invites comments
on various aspects of the proposal to
prohibit undue prejudices and unjust
discrimination as described above.
Please fully explain all views and
alternative solutions or suggestions,
supplying examples and data or other
information to support those views
where possible. Parties who wish to
comment anonymously may do so by
entering ‘‘N/A’’ in the fields that would
identify the commenter. While
comments on any aspect of the
proposed rule are welcome, AMS
specifically solicits comments on the
following.
Undue Prejudices and Unjust
Discrimination
1. Would the regulatory protections
provided by the prohibition on undue
prejudices for market vulnerable
individuals and cooperatives, as
described above, assist those producers
and growers in overcoming barriers to
market access or equitable and
reasonable treatment, or otherwise
address prejudices or the threat thereof
in the marketplace? If so, why? If not,
why not?
2. With respect to undue prejudices,
are the proposed prohibited bases of
market vulnerable individuals and
cooperatives broad enough to provide
appropriate flexibility and ensure
equitable market access? If not, please
suggest changes.
3. Should AMS delineate specific
examples of groups that are market
vulnerable? If so, please provide
supportive evidence regarding historical
adverse treatment of such groups.
4. Should AMS delineate specific
forms of prejudice, such as racial,
ethnic, gender, or religious prejudices,
that would apply for producers who are
members of the relevant group without
regard to their individual qualities?
5. Is the proposed list of undue
prejudices appropriately clear and
inclusive—for example, is it sufficiently
clear that prejudices relating to gender
include sexual orientation?
6. As an alternative or in addition to
the market vulnerable individual
approach, should AMS prohibit
discrimination based on protected
classes (i.e., prohibit discrimination on
the basis of race, color, national origin,
religion, sex, sexual orientation,
disability, age, marital status, family/
parental status, income derived from a
public assistance program, political
E:\FR\FM\03OCP3.SGM
03OCP3
lotter on DSK11XQN23PROD with PROPOSALS3
60030
Federal Register / Vol. 87, No. 190 / Monday, October 3, 2022 / Proposed Rules
beliefs, or gender identity)? Why or why
not?
7. Should prejudices be more
specifically delineated in the
rulemaking to cover some or all of the
bases governing non-discrimination in
conducted programs as discussed in the
section on specific proposed bases, and
specifically: race, color, national origin,
religion, sex, sexual orientation,
disability, age, marital status, family/
parental status, income derived from a
public assistance program, political
beliefs, or gender identity? Why or why
not?
8. With respect to undue prejudices,
should localities be addressed in any
special way, such as localities where
producers or growers are underserved or
otherwise face persistent challenges of
equitable and reasonable market access
owing to the locality or related reasons?
Please provide specific examples, if
possible.
9. What specific challenges or
burdens may regulated entities face in
complying with the undue prejudices
provisions of the proposed rule? How
do they differ from existing policies,
procedures, and practices of regulated
entities?
10. Should AMS clarify how
producers and growers demonstrate
qualification for the protections as
market vulnerable individuals in a local
market? If so, what factors should be
included?
11. Are the specific prejudicial acts
specified in proposed § 201.304(a)(2)
appropriate? Are there additional forms
of prejudicial conduct that should be
specifically delineated? If so, please
identify them and provide examples of
how such actions have been used to
target market vulnerable individuals or
cooperatives.
12. Are there different types of
purchase arrangements than those
generally or ordinarily offered, such as
forward contracts, formula contracts,
other alternative marketing agreements,
or cash market purchases, which could
be employed in a prejudicial manner as
a class of contract or in specific
circumstances? If so, please identify
them and provide examples of how such
actions have been used to target market
vulnerable individuals or cooperatives.
13. Does the undue prejudices
provision provide sufficient protection
regardless of the type of business
organization of the covered producer? If
not, please suggest specific changes.
14. Should prejudicial discrimination
and retaliation provisions be extended
to all persons buying or selling meat and
meat food products, including poultry,
in markets subject to the Act? Why or
why not?
VerDate Sep<11>2014
20:25 Sep 30, 2022
Jkt 259001
15. Does the proposed rule
appropriately enable the production of
religiously compliant meats? Do any
concerns turn on whether the prohibited
prejudices in proposed § 201.304(a)(1)
are defined to include religious bases?
Please explain your views and suggest
specific approaches to address any
concerns.
16. Do the provisions on undue
prejudice adequately address concerns
regarding inequitable market access for
Tribal members and Tribes? If not, what
additional changes should be proposed?
17. How should AMS handle Tribal
government entities that sponsor or
manage regulated entities? Should AMS
permit compliance with proposed
§ 201.304(a) be substituted for
compliance with Tribal government
rules, policies, or guidance governing
equitable market access?
18. AMS is aware of at least one
private industry program aimed at
establishing preferences intended to
create ‘‘a more equitable agricultural
economy’’—in response to ‘‘systemic
inequality’’—by partnering with Black
producers.118 Were such a program (or
a similar program designed to address
socially inclusive supply chains)
present in livestock and poultry
markets, should AMS evaluate and
determine that such program is an
undue preference pursuant to the
criteria set forth in 9 CFR 201.211?
Please explain views and offer
suggestions on ways to address relevant
concerns.
19. Does the proposed regulation
provide appropriate protection for
cooperatives, in particular as the
structure and organization of
cooperatives vary across livestock and
poultry markets? Please explain any
particular concerns that should be better
addressed by the proposed regulation.
20. Prejudice and other prohibited
actions the agency proposes refers to
offering contract terms that are less
favorable than those generally or
ordinarily offered. Should the agency be
more specific to include differential
contract terms, such as: price terms,
including any base or formula price;
formulas used for premiums or
discounts related to grade, yield,
quality, or specific characteristics of the
animals or meat; the duration of the
commitment to purchase or to contract
for the production of animals;
transportation requirements; delivery
location requirements; delivery date and
time requirements; terms related to who
determines date of delivery; the
118 Cargill’s ‘‘Black Farmer Equity Initiative’’:
https://www.cargill.com/about/black-farmer-equityinitiative (last accessed 8/9/2022).
PO 00000
Frm 00022
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
required number of animals to be
delivered; layout periods in production
contracts; financing, risk-sharing, and
profit-sharing; or terms related to the
companies’ provision of inputs or
services, grower compensation, and
capital investment requirements under
production contracts? Please explain
why or why not, and what terms the
agency could add or change.
21. Should the Agency include among
the prejudices, the action of offering less
favorable price terms, contract terms,
and other less favorable treatment in the
course of business dealings than those
generally offered to similarly situated
producers? Should an allowance be
made for legitimate business reasons?
Please explain why or why not, and
what terms the Agency could add or
change.
Retaliation
22. Would the regulatory protections
provided by the prohibition on
retaliation, as described above, assist
producers and growers in avoiding
unjust discrimination in the market or
otherwise help them access markets,
obtain meaningful and accurate price
discovery, or avoid anticompetitive or
unjust practices or the threats thereof? If
so, why; if not, why not?
23. Are the specific acts of retaliation
listed in proposed § 201.304(b)(3)
appropriate? Are there additional forms
of retaliatory conduct that should be
specifically delineated?
24. Should prohibitions on retaliation
protect producers and growers who
choose not to participate in protected
activities? For example, should the
provision prohibit the giving of any
premiums or discounts with respect to
joining or not joining livestock or
poultry associations?
25. Are the bases of protected
activities appropriate, including their
nexus to the business, industry, and
community, criteria for selection, and
application of those criteria? Should
they be broader, narrower, or different
in some way? Please explain your
views.
26. Should the protected activities
relating to communication and
cooperation, beyond government
entities, be limited to USDA extension
and USDA supported (grantees and
cooperators) non-profit entities? Why or
why not?
27. Does the proposed anti-retaliation
provision provide sufficient protection
regardless of the covered producer’s
type of business organization? If not,
please suggest specific changes.
28. Should protections for exploring a
business relationship be extended to
such activities with any person, or
E:\FR\FM\03OCP3.SGM
03OCP3
Federal Register / Vol. 87, No. 190 / Monday, October 3, 2022 / Proposed Rules
lotter on DSK11XQN23PROD with PROPOSALS3
should they be limited, as they are in
the proposal, to exploring a business
relationship with a regulated entity?
29. Should the proposed list of
retaliatory actions include a catch-all
clause, such as ‘‘offering unfavorable
contract terms that otherwise effect
reprisal’’ or ‘‘offering contract terms that
are less favorable than those generally or
ordinarily offered’’? That is, is the
offering of a contract term a proper
subject of retaliation? If so, should we
also include a non-exclusive list of
contract terms that could affect reprisal,
such as price terms, including any base
or formula price; formulas used for
premiums or discounts related to grade,
yield, quality, or specific characteristics
of the animals or meat; the duration of
the commitment to purchase or to
contract for the production of animals;
transportation requirements; delivery
location requirements; delivery date and
time requirements; terms related to who
determines date of delivery; the
required number of animals to be
delivered; layout periods in production
contracts; financing, risk-sharing, and
profit-sharing; or terms related to the
companies’ provision of inputs or
services, grower compensation, or
capital investment requirements under
production contracts? Please explain
why or why not, and what terms the
agency could add or change.
30. What specific challenges or
burdens might regulated entities face in
complying with the anti-retaliation
provisions of the proposed rule? How
do the proposed provisions differ from
existing policies, procedures, and
practices of regulated entities?
Recordkeeping
31. Are the recordkeeping obligations
of the proposed regulation appropriate
to permit AMS to monitor regulated
entities for compliance? Why or why
not, and what changes, if any, should be
made?
32. Should AMS require regulated
entities to produce and maintain
specific policies and procedures,
specific compliance practices or
certifications, or specific disclosures to
help ensure compliance with the undue
prejudices and anti-retaliation
provisions of the proposed rule? Please
explain why for specific items.
33. What specific challenges or
burdens might regulated entities face in
complying with recordkeeping duties of
the proposed rule? How do they differ
from existing policies, procedures, and
practices of regulated entities?
III. Deceptive Practices
AMS also proposes a new § 201.306
designed to prohibit regulated entities
VerDate Sep<11>2014
20:25 Sep 30, 2022
Jkt 259001
from specified deceptive practices in
contracting. Because of the power of the
regulated entities over their vertical
relationships, deceptions in contracting
are of considerable concern.
Similar to its broad prohibition of
unjustly discriminatory practices, the
Act does not specifically define the
‘‘deceptive practices’’ it prohibits in sec.
202(a). The agency’s interpretation of
‘‘deceptive practices’’ here relates to
trends underlying the Act’s passage. At
the time of the Act’s passage, state
common law already prohibited
deceptive practices, such as fraudulent
inducement of contract and
misattribution of the source of goods.
These are not, as the Act is not, limited
to deceived and injured contracting
parties, but also include deceptions that
directly injure competitors. Regardless,
courts were cautiously expanding
common law beyond misrepresentations
of source to misrepresentations
concerning other characteristics or
qualities of the seller’s goods.119
Likewise, in 1920—shortly before the
passage of the Act—Congress passed a
Federal trademark law that prohibited
intentional deception regarding the
origin of goods. Public Law 66–163, 41
Stat. 534 (1920). So, in 1921, the Act
was one of the earliest Federal
prohibitions against deceptive practices.
It did not remain so for long.
Less than a decade after the passage
of the Act, in 1930, the Perishable
Agricultural Commodities Act followed
with its prohibitions against ‘‘deceptive
practices in connection with the
weighing, counting, or in any way
determining the quantity of any
perishable agricultural commodity
received, bought, sold, shipped, or
handled in interstate or foreign
commerce.’’ See 7 U.S.C. 499b. In 1938,
the Federal Trade Commission Act was
amended to declare unlawful
‘‘deceptive acts or practices in or
affecting commerce.’’ Public Law 75–
447, 52 Stat. 111 (1938). As observed in
1967, ‘‘[d]eceptive trade practices
victimize honest merchants as well as
consumers, and impair rational
allocation of economic resources.’’ 120
The FTC has characterized deception as:
involving a material representation,
omission or practice that is likely to
mislead a consumer acting reasonably in
the circumstances.121
119 Restatement (Third) of Unfair Competition sec.
2 (1995), comment b.
120 Richard F. Dole, Jr., Merchant and Consumer
Protection: The Uniform Deceptive Trade Practices
Act, 76 Yale L.J. 485 (1967).
121 Federal Trade Commission, Policy Statement
on Deception, 1983, available at https://
www.ftc.gov/legal-library/browse/ftc-policystatement-deception (last accessed Aug. 2022).
PO 00000
Frm 00023
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
60031
‘‘[I]ntegrity and ethics of those
engaged in marketing livestock’’ is a
vital concern.122 With respect to
regulating deception, the supply of meat
to the American consumer depends on
a market that is safe, reliable, and
honest.123 Protecting the market from
the harms of deception starts with
protecting suppliers: producers, market
agencies, dealers, and packers. To
achieve a market free of deceptive
practices, the Secretary has established
regulations and pursued administrative
and Federal enforcement cases.
In the case law and through
regulations, as described below,
violative deceptions under the Act
include false statements or omissions
that occur even before contracting that
prevent or mislead sellers or buyers
from making an informed decision.
Thus, obvious falsehoods, such as false
weighing and false accounting have
always been considered deceptive
practices under sec. 202(a) of the Act.
Another obvious falsehood, delivering
checks drawn on accounts with
insufficient funds—whether for
livestock or meat—is also deceptive.
Moreover, the Act requires honest
dealing, so misleading omissions are
also prohibited. Prohibited omissions
include failure to tell a business partner
that the regulated entity was receiving a
commission from a competitor, sales
tactics that omit relevant information, or
failure to have the required bond. And
finally, where regulated entities have
close business relationships, secret
payments and bribes undermine the
ability of producers and consumers to
rely on an honest market and are
therefore deceptive.
This proposed regulation would not
be the first to prohibit deception.
Current Packers and Stockyards
regulations require honesty in weighing
(§§ 201.49, 201.71), price reporting
(§ 201.53), fees (§ 201.98), and business
relationships (§ 201.67). Even in the
consideration of whether termination of
a contract violated the Act, AMS
currently considers the quality of the
communication, and therefore considers
its honesty. (See § 201.217.)
Producers and consumers cannot
make rational decisions in a dishonest
market, and honest competitors cannot
compete when regulated entities
deceive. For example, if one packer is
paying more for livestock by weight but
is also deceptively weighing livestock to
lower the total value of the livestock
during processing, the honest packer
122 See, e.g., Midwest Farmers v. United States, 64
F. Supp. 91, 95 (D. Minn. 1945).
123 In re: Frosty Morn Meats, Inc., 7 B.R. 988, 1020
(M.D. Tenn. 1980).
E:\FR\FM\03OCP3.SGM
03OCP3
lotter on DSK11XQN23PROD with PROPOSALS3
60032
Federal Register / Vol. 87, No. 190 / Monday, October 3, 2022 / Proposed Rules
must compete with that deception. On
the other hand, if the weight of livestock
from a packer were to be regularly more
favorable, due to falsely increasing the
weight, honest competitors would have
to respond to a reputation that their
weights are lower. A packer that fails to
pay for meat promptly is not only
deceiving the seller—by financing their
operations using the seller’s goods—but
is also forcing honest meat packers to
compete without financing their
operations in this deceptive manner.
Proposed § 201.306—Deceptive
practices—would name practices and
devices that AMS considers deceptive
in violation of sec. 202(a) of the Act,
which prohibits deceptive practices and
devices by packers, swine contractors,
and live poultry dealers. AMS intends
that this proposed regulation would
address broad areas of specific concern,
but it may not exhaustively identify all
deceptive practices that would violate
sec. 202(a) of the Act.
As outlined extensively in the
separately proposed transparency rule,
poultry growers face incomplete
information regarding contracting and
tournaments and have complained of
inaccurate information influencing their
decisions to be growers or make
additional capital investments. While
AMS has separately proposed specific
disclosures relating to transparency in
poultry growing contracts and
tournaments in another proposed rule,
Transparency in Poultry Growing
Contracting and Tournaments, 87 FR
34980 (June 8, 2022), the provisions of
this proposed rule are broader. These
provisions also encompass poultry
growing contracting and tournaments;
for example, this proposed rule would
address communications by the live
poultry dealer and its agents in the
context of contracting or tournaments.
Further, this rulemaking addresses
deception in hog and cattle markets,
which is not addressed in the proposed
transparency rule.
The provisions of this proposed rule
would also focus on general
circumstances that may give rise to the
provision of false or misleading
information in the production or
growing of poultry or livestock. Such
circumstances could include where a
live poultry dealer’s poultry nutrition
adviser provides misleading advice to a
contract grower, where a swine
production contract provides false
information regarding manure
compliance procedures, or where a
packer provides false or misleading
information about cash market trading
in livestock.
These proposed provisions respond,
in part, to the range of complaints
VerDate Sep<11>2014
20:25 Sep 30, 2022
Jkt 259001
lodged with USDA, Congress, and the
media over the years regarding
inaccurate, incomplete, or otherwise
misleading representations or pretexts
that affect the decision-making or access
to markets by producers and growers of
livestock and poultry. For example,
packers and industry representatives
have routinely indicated that producers
may choose the form of pricing
mechanism for their transactions.
However, as cash-negotiated markets
have declined, producers have
increasingly complained to USDA that
they are not provided such a choice, and
in fact are commonly given a take-it-orleave-it offer to buy their cattle off of a
pricing formula provided by the
company. Producers have complained
that they have been told their cattle are
not of sufficiently high quality or that
formula market arrangements are
necessary to incentivize such quality,
but cattle procured under those
marketing arrangements may not in fact
be of any higher quality. This raises
legitimate concerns that certain refusals
to deal are based upon pretext or
deception, which hinders the free flow
of livestock from producer to consumer.
If producers have been misled, they are
hindered from organizing their
operations so that they can correctly
identify competitor packers that will
accept their livestock or otherwise
contract with them.
Poultry growers have complained
over the years regarding unfavorable
provision of inputs made to certain
producers despite statements by live
poultry dealers that there are no
differences in treatment. Growers have
also complained of terminations,
suspensions, or reductions in flocks on
the basis of pretext, such as animal
welfare contractual violations, when in
fact other reasons may exist for the
termination, including but not limited
to the discrimination and retaliation
noted above, or other unreasonable
bases such as a preference for family or
friends of the local agent of a live
poultry dealer or for a poultry grower
connected to a senior executive of a live
poultry dealer.124 If misleading
information in connection with a
termination is provided to a bank that
forecloses on the grower, this may be
actionable as well by the grower who
was the victim of the deception. While
this would not necessarily be an undue
preference or unjust discrimination, it
would be covered by this deception
rulemaking. Therefore, the proposed
rule supports market integrity more
broadly by ensuring that producers and
124 Wheeler v. Pilgrim’s Pride, 536 F.3d 455 (5th
Cir. 2008).
PO 00000
Frm 00024
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
growers can make decisions and operate
in the market based on complete and
accurate information.
Hog producers and growers, as well as
cattle producers, have also highlighted
concerns regarding preferential market
access for company-owned or controlled
livestock. Again, while this part of the
proposed rule would not prohibit undue
preferences, this deception rulemaking
would establish a clearer duty on
regulated entities regarding honesty and
market integrity in the relationships
with covered producers, including with
respect to statements made regarding
market access and other aspects of
contracting.
The high levels of oligopsony in the
local marketplaces in which many
producers and growers operate today,
and the extensive reliance on vertical
integration, forward contracting, and
long-term marking agreements, mean
that producers and growers are more
vulnerable to being excluded from, or to
suffering adverse pricing in, the
marketplace by these deceptions in
contracting, if and where they may
arise.
More than 100 years of history
illustrate the types of conduct
prohibited as deceptive by the Act,
which provide a foundation for some of
the specific deceptions that this
proposed rule addresses. The FTC
employed a similar approach when
developing its policy on deceptive
practices. Recognizing that there was no
single definitive statement of the FTC’s
authority on ‘‘deceptive acts or
practices,’’ it reviewed its own history
of decided cases to identify the most
important principles of general
applicability and provide a greater sense
of certainty as to how the concept of
deception will be applied. The FTC’s
approach informs AMS in identifying
and prohibiting deceptive practices.
Past cases indicate that USDA’s
approach, generally, is to view
representations, omissions, and
practices from the perspective of a
reasonable party receiving them and
determine if those deceptions affect the
conduct or decision of the recipient. As
the court explained in Gerace v. Utica
Veal Co., 580 F. Supp. 1465, 1469
(N.D.N.Y. 1984), regulated entities are
liable to anyone for the damages they
sustain in consequence of an entity’s
deceptive practice, even if they are not
a direct party to the transaction.
AMS believes that a substantial arc of
deceptive practices in the marketplace
that this specific rulemaking intends to
prohibit can be organized and
summarized as deceptions in contract
formation, contract operation, contract
cancellation, and refusals to contract.
E:\FR\FM\03OCP3.SGM
03OCP3
Federal Register / Vol. 87, No. 190 / Monday, October 3, 2022 / Proposed Rules
Deceptions in the contracting process
present harms that cause the type of
injury the Act was designed to prevent.
This proposed regulation addresses
these four types of deceptions.
lotter on DSK11XQN23PROD with PROPOSALS3
A. Scope of Deceptive Practices
Regulated
Proposed § 201.306(a), Deceptive
practices, sets forth the scope of the
prohibition of deceptive practices in the
rest of § 201.306. The P&S Act limits the
Secretary’s jurisdiction to the regulated
entities’ operations subject to the P&S
Act. Thus, the proposed regulation’s
scope relates to those operations with
respect to livestock, meats, meat food
products, livestock products in
unmanufactured form, or live poultry.
B. Deceptive Practices in the Offering or
Formation of Contract
Proposed § 201.306(b) would prohibit
a regulated entity from making or
modifying a contract when the entity
employs a pretext, false or misleading
statement, or fails to state a material fact
necessary to make the statement made
not otherwise false or misleading.
Therefore, this proposed regulation is
intended to prevent deception in
contract offering or formation.
Deception in the offering or formation
of a contract has taken many forms
through the Act’s history. One example
is false advertising, specifically bait and
switch advertising, which occurs
through advertising on price when, in
fact, the customer has to pay a higher
price at the point of sale. This practice
is illegal under both the P&S Act and
the FTC Act. In the case under the P&S
Act, In re: Larry W. Peterman, d/b/a
Meat Masters, 42 Agric. Dec. 1848
(1983), aff’d Peterman v. United States
Dep’t of Agric, 770 F.2d 888 (10th Cir.
1985), the packer advertised meat at a
very attractive low price. Customers
responded to the advertised price, only
to be subjected to deceptive sales
tactics, causing them to purchase higher
priced meats. The advertised meat was
‘‘so fat [the customer] could see very
little red muscle tissue in it,’’ causing
the customer to purchase primal cuts
rather than what they intended to buy
because the packer represented that the
fat loss and yield would be a better
option. After their purchase, customers
determined that they had paid
significantly more than they were led to
believe, and they could have paid much
less even at retail grocery stores.
Under certain circumstances, failures
to disclose information are also
deceptive. The Act’s purposes include
protecting farmers and ranchers from
receiving less than fair market value for
their livestock and protecting
VerDate Sep<11>2014
20:25 Sep 30, 2022
Jkt 259001
consumers from unfair practices.
Solomon Valley Feedlot, Inc. v. Butz,
557 F.2d 717, 718 (10th Cir. 1977).
‘‘Among the means employed to
accomplish this purpose is the use of
surety bonds.’’ Id. at 720. Sellers of
livestock are entitled to the protection of
a packer, dealer, or market agency’s
surety bond securing its obligations.
Failure to maintain an adequate bond is
therefore a deceptive practice.125 When
a packer fails to maintain a bond, the
seller does not know that the sale is
unsecured, and therefore the seller is at
greater risk of nonpayment.
Deception in contract formation is not
limited to false statements and
omissions with respect to regulatory
requirements. The Act includes
affirmative duties to be truthful. For
instance, a court has recognized that the
P&S Act prohibits a regulated entity
from negotiating using published prices
it knows are inaccurate because using
incorrect prices deceives the livestock
seller. See Schumacher v. Tyson Fresh
Meats, Inc., 434 F.Supp.2d 748 (Dist.
S.D. 2006). In Schumacher, the packer
failed to disclose inaccurately reported
boxed beef prices when it negotiated the
purchase of cattle on the basis of those
prices. Because the Act prohibits
deceptive practices with respect to the
price paid to the producer, the court
found that those deceptive practices do
not need to adversely affect competition
to violate the Act. Id.
Likewise, Bruhn’s Freezer Meats of
Chicago, Inc. v. U.S. Dept. of
Agriculture, 438 F.2d 1332 (8th Cir.
1971), affirmed that a variety of
deceptions violate the Act, including
short weighing, misrepresenting grades
and cuts of meat, and false advertising
in the selling of meat to customers. The
agency’s proposed regulation with
respect to deceptive practices in
contract formation prohibits all these
types of deception.
More importantly, AMS is concerned
that transparency in market
transactions—reported prices, offered
contracts, and long-term contracts—is
inhibited by potentially deceptive
practices and statements. AMS has long
received complaints regarding
statements that entice producers to
contract to their eventual detriment.
This provision would make clear that
statements at the time of contract
formation will be evaluated to
determine if there is deception in order
125 United States v. Hulings, 484 F. Supp. 562,
567 (D. Kan. 1980). See also In Re: Mid-W. Veal
Distributors, 43 Agric. Dec. 1124, 1139–40 (1984),
citing In re: Norwich Veal and Beef, Inc., 38 Agric.
Dec. 214 (1979), In Re: Raskin Packing Co., 37
Agric. Dec. 1890, 1894–6 (1978).
PO 00000
Frm 00025
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
60033
to prevent injury to the producers in
their inception.
C. Deceptive Practices in the Operation
of Contract
Proposed § 201.306(c) would prohibit
a regulated entity from performing
under or enforcing a contract by
employing a pretext, false or misleading
statement, or omission of a material fact
necessary to make the statement not
false or misleading.
Deceptive practices take many forms
throughout the operation of a contract.
USDA and the courts have recognized
these forms in a variety of
administrative and Federal enforcement
actions, including false weighing, false
or deceptive grading (including failure
to disclose the formulas for determining
payment), commercial bribery, and
failing to pay for purchases.
False or inaccurate weighing has long
been recognized as deceptive under
secs. 202(a) and 312 of the Act. See
Bruhn’s Freezer Meats, 438 F.3d 1337
(8th Cir. 1971); Solomon Valley Feedlot,
557 F.2d at 717; Gerace v. Utica Veal
Co., 580 F. Supp. 1465, 1470 (N.D.N.Y.
1984). False weighing can occur in
various ways. In some cases, the
regulated entity records inaccurate
weights using an improperly calibrated
scale. In other cases, a regulated entity
uses the scale improperly. Among
examples where packers have been
found to have committed this deceptive
practice, in in re: DuQuoin Packing
Company, Decatur Packing Division and
William S. Martin, 41 Agric. Dec. 1367
(1982), a weigher committed a deceptive
practice when he failed to properly
adjust an otherwise properly working
scale to a zero balance prior to
weighing, which caused the scale to
register less than actual weights.
Weighing is ‘‘a serious matter and one
of paramount importance to the farmer,
industry and consumers.’’ In re Trenton
Livestock, Inc., 33 Agric. Dec. 499, 510
aff’d 510 F.2d 966 (4th Cir. 1975). Even
if a regulated entity does not
intentionally set out to deceive with
respect to the weight of livestock, the
Act does not require proof of a
particularized intent. Parchman v. U.S.
Dep’t of Agric., 852 F.2d 858, 864 (6th
Cir. 1988) (interpreting sec. 312 of the
Act). Short weighing alone is enough to
be an unfair and deceptive practice
under the Act, without regard to the
competitive injury the short weighing
causes. Garace, 580 F. Supp. at 1470.
False or inaccurate grading has the
same effect as false weighing because
deceptive grading prevents the seller
from receiving the full value of their
livestock or poultry. USDA’s Judicial
Officer found a deceptive practice when
E:\FR\FM\03OCP3.SGM
03OCP3
60034
Federal Register / Vol. 87, No. 190 / Monday, October 3, 2022 / Proposed Rules
lotter on DSK11XQN23PROD with PROPOSALS3
a packer failed to inform hog producers
of a change in the formula it used to
estimate lean percent in hogs. Lean
percent was one factor used in
determining price when the packer
purchased hogs on a carcass merit basis.
USDA determined that nearly twenty
thousand lots of hogs were purchased
under the changed formula without
notice to producers, resulting in
payment of $1.8 million less than they
would have received under the previous
formula. In re: Excel Corporation, 63
Agric. Dec. 317 (2004), aff’d Excel Corp.
v. United States Dep’t of Agric., 397
F.3d 1285, 1293 (10th Cir. 2005). This
type of deceptive practice harms honest
competitors because ‘‘[h]ad hog
producers been alerted to the change,
they could have shopped their hogs to
other packers.’’ 397 F.3d at 1291.
Paying ‘‘kickbacks’’ and commercial
bribery may occur both in the contract
formation and during the operation of a
contract. Whether the payment comes
before or after the contract was formed,
those payments are a deceptive practice.
For example, in Holiday Food Serv., Inc.
v. Dep’t of Agric., 820 F.2d 1103, 1105
(9th Cir. 1987), a packer paid the
purchasing agents of hotels and
restaurants ‘‘kickbacks’’ after they
purchased meats for their principals.
And, in Nat’l Beef Packing Co. v. Sec’y
of Agric., 605 F.2d 1167, 1168 (10th Cir.
1979), not only was the commercial
bribery a violation of the Act, but the
court also agreed with the Secretary that
a packer’s executives had a positive
duty to inquire into the payment of
commissions that served as bribes. Id.
Payment violations can be deceptive,
especially issuance of insufficient funds
checks. E.g. In Re: Mid-W. Veal
Distributors, d/b/a Nagle Packing Co., &
Milton Nagle, 43 Agric. Dec. 1124, 1140
(1984). Failing to pay for meat has also
been found to be deceptive in numerous
instances.126 Under the similar language
of sec. 312 of the Act, the Eighth Circuit
explained that timely payment was
unfair and deceptive even prior to the
126 See, e.g. Milton Abeles, Inc. v. Creekstone
Farms Premium Beef, LLC, No. 06–CV–
3893(JFB)(AKT), 2009 WL 875553, at *19 (E.D.N.Y.
Mar. 30, 2009) (citing Liberty Mutual Ins. Co. v.
Bankers Trust Co., 758 F.Supp. 890, 896 n. 7
(S.D.N.Y.1991); In re FLA Packing & Provision, Inc.,
and C. Elliot Kane, P & S Docket No. D–95–0062,
1997 WL 809036, at *6 n. 1 (1997); In re: Central
Packing Co., Inc. d/b/a Plat–Central Food Services
Co., Inc., a/k/a Plat–Central Food Service Supply
Co., and Albert Brust, an individual, 48 Agric. Dec.
290, 297–99 (1989)); see also In Re: Ampex Meats
Corp. & Laurence B. Greenburg., 47 Agric. Dec.
1123, 1125 (1988) (citing In Re: Rotches Pork
Packers, Inc. & David A. Rotches., 46 Agric. Dec.
573, 579–80 (U.S.D.A. Apr. 13, 1987) In Re: George
Ash, 22 Agric. Dec. 889 (1963); In re Goldring
Packing Co., 21 Agric. Dec. 26 (1962); In Re: Eastern
Meats, Inc., 21 Agric. Dec. 580 134 (1962)).
VerDate Sep<11>2014
20:25 Sep 30, 2022
Jkt 259001
enactment of sec. 409 of the Act:
‘‘Timely payment in a livestock
purchase prevents the seller from being
forced, in effect, to finance the
transaction.’’ Van Wyk v. Bergland, 570
F.2d 701, 704 (8th Cir. 1978).
The live poultry dealer’s honesty is
vitally important to poultry growers.
Because much of the payment system
relies on information that is wholly
within the live poultry dealer’s control,
deception is particularly dangerous. The
Department has received complaints
regarding statements made during the
operation of the contract that led
producers to believe that specific terms
would not be enforced, only to see the
live poultry dealer implement policy
changes that led to immediate changes
to contracting requirements. These sorts
of communications may reach the level
of unlawful deception under the P&S
Act, which reaches beyond commonlaw fraud. Likewise, for the market to
function, livestock producers must be
able to reasonably rely on a packer’s
calculation of value, and they must be
able to rely on statements and
accountings the packers deliver.
D. Deceptive Practices in the
Termination of Contract
Proposed § 201.306(d) would prohibit
regulated entities from terminating a
contractortaking any otheradverse
action against a covered producer by
employing pretext, false or misleading
statements, or omission to state a
material fact necessary to make the
statement not false or misleading.
AMS notes, for example, that poultry
growers complain of companies
terminating their broiler production
contracts based on pretext or for a
deceptive reason. Contract termination
puts the grower at severe risk of
significant economic loss. A production
broiler house often has significant longterm financial obligations. The potential
loss includes not only the loss of
production income, but construction is
often financed with mortgages on the
grower’s farm or family home.
Pretextual cancellation may make even
the sale or transfer of the broiler
production house impossible because
purchasers may be unable to determine
if the broiler houses have value.
E. Deceptive Practices in Refusal To
Deal
Proposed § 201.306(e) would prohibit
the deceptive practice of providing false
or misleading information to a producer,
grower, or association of producers or
growers concerning the regulated
entity’s refusal to contract. AMS
proposes this ban to meet producer
concerns that packers use pretext to
PO 00000
Frm 00026
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
deny access to certain livestock
transactions and pretextual refusals to
renew growing contracts. This proposal
also supports the statutory prohibition
in sec. 202(a) of the Act of unjust
discrimination and the sec. 202(b)
prohibition of undue preferences and
prejudices. A refusal to contract may be
lawful or unlawful. So, while an
ordinary refusal to deal is not a
violation of the Act, some refusals have
unlawful purposes or effects. Group
boycott, for example, has unlawful
purpose and effect. See Klor’s, Inc. v.
Broadway-Hale Stores, Inc., 359 U.S.
207 (1959). Group boycott—or blanket
refusal to deal—forces the boycotted
party to adopt conforming trade
practices, or they must quit the business
entirely. Id. Under the P&S Act,
unlawful practices have included
attempts to force livestock markets to
adopt terms that were favorable to the
packer. See De Jong Packing Co. v. U.S.
Dep’t of Agric., 618 F.2d 1329, 1336 (9th
Cir. 1980). Packers may not ‘‘exert a
coercive influence upon the trade
practices of third parties in order to
exact more favorable terms than they
could otherwise obtain.’’ Id. Moreover,
refusal to deal was firmly on the minds
of the legislature when the Act passed.
61 Cong. Rec. 1861 (1921) (explaining
that packers refused to bid on a load of
cattle in more than one market, thereby
preventing sellers from re-consigning
livestock to different markets).
Deceptions related to these refusals to
deal may conceal other unlawful
practices designed to pose barriers to
entry for farmers that may wish to enter
these markets.
A regulated entity that refused to
contract on unlawful grounds may well
choose to hide their motives with
misleading or deceptive statements.
This proposed regulation would
recognize misleading statements in a
refusal to enter into a contract as
‘‘deceptive’’ within the meaning of the
Act.
F. Request for Comments on Proposed
§ 201.306
AMS invites comment on (1) the
proposed addition of new § 201.306 to
the regulations and (2) the specific
proposed prohibitions on deceptive
practices. Parties who wish to comment
anonymously may do so by entering ‘‘N/
A’’ in the fields that would identify the
commenter. While comments on any
aspect of the proposed new section are
welcome, AMS specifically solicits
comments on the following:
1. Do the proposed regulations
accurately and adequately identify
recurrent deceptive practices in the
livestock and poultry industries? Please
E:\FR\FM\03OCP3.SGM
03OCP3
lotter on DSK11XQN23PROD with PROPOSALS3
Federal Register / Vol. 87, No. 190 / Monday, October 3, 2022 / Proposed Rules
explain why or why not and explain in
detail any areas of deception that may
be missing.
2. Are there recurrent deceptive
practices that are not adequately
addressed by these regulations? Please
discuss.
3. Should deception in contract
refusal be governed by the categorical
approach as proposed, or should it be
governed by a single statement setting
out one standard for contract formation,
performance, and termination? Why or
why not?
4. Should deception be structured
instead around prohibiting the
deceptive pretext, statement, or
omission, rather than prohibiting the
contractual activity based on the
deceptive statement or omission? Why
or why not?
5. Do the prohibitions against
‘‘employing’’ certain false or misleading
statements, pretexts, and omissions in
the formation, operation, etc., of a
contract appropriately capture the
importance or effect of the misleading
statement (its materiality or relevance to
the producer or the formation/
operation/etc., of the contract)? Or
should a regulated entity be prohibited
from employing any pretext, false or
misleading statement, or omission of
material facts necessary to make a
statement not false or misleading, in
connection with making, enforcing, or
cancelling contact? In either case, if not,
how could AMS better approach this
issue, including using elements or
defenses?
6. Are there other elements, such as
the reasonableness of the recipient, that
AMS should explicitly consider in a
rule on deception? Why or why not?
7. What specific challenges or
burdens might regulated entities face in
complying with the deceptive practices
provisions of the proposed rule? How
do they differ from existing policies,
procedures, and practices of regulated
entities?
8. Should AMS propose specific
recordkeeping provisions relating to
these deceptive practices? If so, what
should they include?
9. Should AMS require that all
contracts with respect to livestock,
meats, meat food products, livestock
products in unmanufactured form, or
live poultry be in writing? Why or why
not?
10. Do the provisions on deception
provide sufficiently clarity regarding
deception with respect to a regulated
entity’s course of business dealings
generally or ordinarily offered? If not,
how might such a provision be
structured?
VerDate Sep<11>2014
20:25 Sep 30, 2022
Jkt 259001
11. Should a failure to continue to
buy in the cash market, following a
regular or dependable pattern or
practice of such buying, be treated for
the purposes of this proposed rule as
more similar to termination of a
contract, rather than as refusal to deal?
Why or why not?
IV. Severability
AMS proposes to add a new § 201.390
to 9 CFR part 201 of the Packers and
Stockyards regulations. This provision
would ensure that if any provision of
part 201 was declared invalid, or if the
applicability of any of its provisions to
any person or circumstances was held
invalid, the validity of the remaining
provisions of part 201 or their
applicability to other persons or
circumstances would not be affected.
Such a provision is typical in AMS
regulations that may cover several
different topics and is proposed for
addition here as a matter of
housekeeping.
V. Required Regulatory Analyses
Paperwork Reduction Act
In accordance with the Paperwork
Reduction Act of 1995 (PRA) (44 U.S.C.
Chapter 35), AMS has requested Office
of Management and Budget (OMB)
approval of the information collection
and recordkeeping requirement of
proposed § 201.304(c). AMS invites
comments on this new information
collection. All comments received on
this information collection will be
summarized and included in the final
request for OMB approval. Below is
detailed information on the burdens of
these new information collection and
recordkeeping requirements. A similar
amount of detail can be found in the
Regulatory Impact Analysis (RIA), as the
recordkeeping costs apply to both the
PRA and the RIA. Comments on this
section will be considered in the final
rule analysis.
OMB Number: 0581–NEW.
Expiration Date of Approval: This is
a NEW collection.
Type of Request: Approval of a New
Information Collection.
Abstract: This rulemaking has been
determined to be significant for the
purposes of Executive Order (E.O.)
12866 and, therefore, has been
accordingly reviewed by the Office of
Management and Budget. As a required
part of the regulatory process, AMS
prepared an economic analysis of the
costs and benefits of the proposed
§§ 201.302, 201.304, 201.306, and
201.390.
In the late 1910s, Congress was
concerned about the monopoly power
PO 00000
Frm 00027
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
60035
wielded by the five large meatpackers
and the consequent constraint to
competition and diminished economic
opportunities for rural communities,
agricultural producers and small food
manufacturers.127 Congress believed the
existing the Sherman Act and Federal
Trade Commission Act was inadequate
in its protections of agricultural
producers.128 Consequently, Congress
expanded and furthered its protections
of farmers and ranchers by enacting the
1921 Packers and Stockyards Act and
giving the Secretary of Agriculture
authority to regulate the meat packing
industry.
Proposed § 201.304(a) ensures full
and non-discriminatory market access
for producers who would be considered
vulnerable to prejudice, disadvantage,
or exclusion from the marketplace. The
provision would also prohibit undue
prejudices and disadvantages based
upon the status of the covered producer
as a cooperative. Proposed § 201.304(b)
would address retaliation by setting out
protected activities that a covered
producer may engage in but that a
regulated entity may not use as grounds
for unjust discrimination or undue
prejudice.
Proposed § 201.304(c)(1) would
require live poultry dealers, swine
contractors, and packers to incur
recordkeeping costs by requiring
regulated entities to retain all relevant
records relating to their compliance
with proposed § 201.304(a) and (b) for
no less than 5 years. AMS is proposing
this information collection and
recordkeeping requirement to assist in
evaluating compliance with proposed
§ 201.304 and to facilitate investigations
and enforcements based on producer
and grower complaints. Costs of
recordkeeping include maintaining and
updating records by regulated entities as
will be discussed and quantified below.
Proposed § 201.304(c)(2) lists records
that may be relevant and that must be
retained if they exist. Specifically,
regulated entities would be required to
retain records relating to policies and
procedures, staff training materials,
materials informing covered producers
regarding reporting mechanisms and
protections, compliance testing, board
of directors’ oversight materials, and the
number and nature of complaints
received relevant to proposed § 201.304.
The information collection and
recordkeeping requirement in this
127 See 61 Cong. Rec. 1860 (1921) (House Floor
Debate).
128 See, Shively, J. and Roberts, J., ‘‘Competition
Under the Packers and Stockyards Act: What
Now?’’ 15 Drake Journal of Agricultural Law 419,
422–423 (2010); and Current Legislation, 22
Columbia Law Review 68, 69 (1922).
E:\FR\FM\03OCP3.SGM
03OCP3
60036
Federal Register / Vol. 87, No. 190 / Monday, October 3, 2022 / Proposed Rules
request may be valuable in reducing
instances of undue prejudices,
discrimination, and retaliation in the
livestock and poultry industries, in
accordance with the purposes of the
P&S Act, 1921. The information
collection request and recordkeeping
requirement may also bolster AMS’s
ability to review the records of regulated
entities during compliance reviews and
investigations based on complaints of
undue prejudices, discrimination, and
retaliation in the livestock and poultry
industries.
lotter on DSK11XQN23PROD with PROPOSALS3
Live Poultry Dealer, Swine Contractor,
and Packer Recordkeeping Costs
Estimate of Burden: Public reporting
burden for maintaining records for this
information collection is estimated to
average 4.25 hours per response in the
first year, and 3.50 hours thereafter.
Respondents: Live poultry dealers,
swine contractors, and packers
Estimated Number of Respondents:
1,026
Estimated Total Annual Burden on
Respondents: 4,361 hours in the first
year and 3,591 hours thereafter.
Comments: Comments are invited on:
(1) Whether the proposed collection of
the information is necessary for the
proper performance of the functions of
the agency, including whether the
information will have practical utility;
(2) the accuracy of the agency’s estimate
of the burden of the proposed collection
of information; (3) ways to enhance the
quality, utility, and clarity of the
information to be collected; and (4)
ways to minimize the burden of the
collection of information on those who
are to respond; including through the
use of appropriate automated,
electronic, mechanical, or other
technological collection techniques or
other forms of information technology.
Information Collection and
Recordkeeping Costs of Proposed
§ 201.304(c)
Costs to comply with the proposed
recordkeeping are likely relatively low.
Proposed § 201.304(c), requires certain
specific records that, if the regulated
entity maintains, should be kept for a
period of five years, including policies
and procedures, staff training materials,
materials informing covered producers
regarding reporting mechanisms and
protections, compliance testing, board
of directors’ oversight materials, and the
number and nature of unduly
prejudicial or discrimination-based
complaints received relevant to
proposed § 201.304(a) and (b).
Costs of recordkeeping include
regulated entities maintaining and
updating compliance records. From the
VerDate Sep<11>2014
20:25 Sep 30, 2022
Jkt 259001
perspective of the regulated entity,
recordkeeping is a direct cost. Some
smaller regulated entities that currently
don’t maintain records, may voluntarily
decide to develop formal policies,
procedures, training, etc., to comply
with the rulemaking and would then
have records to maintain.
AMS expects the recordkeeping costs
would be comprised of the time
required by regulated entities to store
and maintain records. AMS expects that
the costs will be relatively small
because some packers, live poultry
dealers, and swine contractors may
currently have few records concerning
policies and procedures, staff training
materials, materials informing covered
producers regarding reporting
mechanisms and protections,
compliance testing, board of directors’
oversight materials, and the number and
nature of complaints received related to
prejudicial and discriminatory
treatment. Some firms might not have
any records to store. Others already
store the records and may have no new
costs.
The amount of time required to keep
records were estimated by AMS subject
matter experts. These experts were
economists and supervisors with many
years of experience in AMS’s PSD
conducting investigations and
compliance reviews of regulated
entities. AMS used the May 2020 U.S.
Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS)
Occupational Employment and Wage
Statistics for the time values in this
analysis.129 BLS estimated an average
hourly wage for general and operations
managers in animal slaughtering and
processing to be $65.84. The average
hourly wage for lawyers in food
manufacturing was $80.39. In applying
the cost estimates, AMS marked-up the
wages by 41.56 percent to account for
fringe benefits.
AMS expects that recordkeeping costs
would be correlated with the size of the
firms. AMS ranked packers, live poultry
dealers, and swine contractors by size
and grouped them into quartiles,
estimating more recordkeeping time for
the largest entities in the first quartile
than for the smallest entities in the
fourth quartile. The first quartile
contains the largest 25 percent of
entities, and the fourth quartile contains
the smallest 25 percent of entities. AMS
estimated that proposed § 201.304(c)
would require an average of 4.00 hours
of administrative assistant time, 1.50
hours of time each from managers,
129 Estimates are available at U.S. Bureau of Labor
Statistics. Occupational Employment and Wage
Statistics, available at https://www.bls.gov/oes/
special.requests/oesm20all.zip (accessed 8/9/2022).
PO 00000
Frm 00028
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
attorneys, and information technology
staff for packers, live poultry dealers,
and swine contractors in the first
quartile to setup and maintain the
required records in the first year. AMS
expects the packers, live poultry
dealers, and swine contractors in the
second quartile would require an
average of 2.00 hours of administrative
assistant time, 0.75 hours of time each
from managers, attorneys, and
information technology staff for first
year costs. The third quartile would
require 1.33 hours of administrative
assistant time, 0.50 hours of time each
from managers, attorneys, and
information technology staff for first
year costs, and the fourth quartile would
require 0.67 hours of administrative
assistant time, 0.25 hours of time each
from managers, attorneys, and
information technology staff.
AMS also expects that packers, live
poultry dealers, and swine contractors
will incur continuing recordkeeping
costs in each successive year. AMS
estimated that proposed § 201.304(c)
would require an average of 3.00 hours
of administrative assistant time, 1.50
hours of time each from managers,
attorneys, and 1.00 hour of time from
information technology staff for packers,
live poultry dealers, and swine
contractors in the largest quartile to
setup and maintain the required records
in each succeeding year. AMS expects
that packers, live poultry dealers, and
swine contractors in the second quartile
would require an average of 1.50 hours
of administrative assistant time, 0.75
hours of time each from managers,
attorneys, and 0.50 hours of time from
information technology staff in each
succeeding year. The third quartile
would require 1.00 hour of
administrative assistant time, 0.50 hours
of time each from managers, attorneys,
and 0.33 hours of time from information
technology staff in each succeeding
year, and the smallest quartile would
require 0.50 hours of administrative
assistant time, 0.25 hours of time each
from managers, and attorneys, and 0.17
hours from information technology staff.
Estimated first-year costs for
recordkeeping requirements in proposed
§ 201.304(c) totaled $26,000 for live
poultry dealers,130 $170,000 for swine
contractors,131 and $107,000 for
130 89 live poultry dealers x ($39.69 per hour
admin. cost × (4 hours + 2 hours + 1.33 hours +
.67 hours)) + ($93.20 per hour manger cost × (1.5
hours + .75 hours + .5 hours + .25 hours)) +
($113.80 legal cost × (1.5 hours + .75 hours + .5
hours + .25 hours)) + ($82.50 information tech cost
× (1.5 hours + .75 hours + .5 hours + .25 hours))/
4 = $26,390.
131 575 swine contractors × ($39.69 per hour
admin. cost ×(4 hours + 2 hours + 1.33 hours + .67
E:\FR\FM\03OCP3.SGM
03OCP3
Federal Register / Vol. 87, No. 190 / Monday, October 3, 2022 / Proposed Rules
packers.132 Estimated yearly continuing
costs for recordkeeping requirements in
§ 201.304(c) totaled $23,000 for live
poultry dealers,133 $147,000 for swine
contractors,134 and $93,000 for
packers.135
Breaking out costs by market, AMS
expects recordkeeping requirements in
proposed § 201.304(c) to cost beef
packers $47,000 in the first year and
$41,000 in each following year.
Proposed § 201.304(c) would cost lamb
packers $21,000 in the first year and
$18,000 in successive years. Proposed
§ 201.304(c) would cost pork packers
$39,000, and it would cost swine
contractors $170,000 for a total of
$209,000 in the first year. Proposed
§ 201.304(c) would cost swine
contractors $147,000 in successive
years, and it would cost pork packers
$33,000 for a total $180,000.
lotter on DSK11XQN23PROD with PROPOSALS3
Executive Order 12866 and the
Regulatory Flexibility Act
This rulemaking has been determined
to be significant for the purposes of E.O.
12866 and, therefore, has accordingly
reviewed by the Office of Management
and Budget. As a required part of the
regulatory process, AMS prepared an
economic analysis of the costs and
benefits of the proposed §§ 201.302,
201.304, 201.306, and 201.390. This
regulatory filing is comprised of
definitions in § 201.302, specific
prohibited discriminatory and unduly
prejudicial practices in § 201.304,
specific prohibited deceptive practices
hours)) + ($93.20 per hour manger cost × (1.5 hours
+ .75 hours + .5 hours + .25 hours)) + (113.80 legal
cost ×(1.5 hours + .75 hours + .5 hours + .25 hours))
+ ($82.50 information tech cost × (1.5 hours + .75
hours + .5 hours + .25 hours))/4 = $170,496.
132 362 packers × ($39.69 per hour admin. cost ×
(4 hours + 2 hours + 1.33 hours + .67 hours)) +
($93.20 per hour manger cost × (1.5 hours + .75
hours + .5 hours + .25 hours)) + ($113.80 legal cost
× (1.5 hours + .75 hours + .5 hours + .25 hours))
+ ($82.50 information tech cost × (1.5 hours + .75
hours + .5 hours + .25 hours))/4 = $107,338.
133 89 live poultry dealers ×($39.69 per hour
admin. cost × (4 hours + 2 hours + 1.33 hours +
.67 hours)) + ($93.20 per hour manger cost × (1.5
hours + .75 hours + .5 hours + .25 hours)) +
($113.80 legal cost × (1.5 hours + .75 hours + .5
hours + .25 hours)) + $82.50 information tech cost
× (1.5 hours + .75 hours + .5 hours + .25 hours))/
4 = $22,788.
134 575 swine contractors × ($39.69 per hour
admin. cost × (4 hours + 2 hours + 1.33 hours +
.67 hours)) + ($93.20 per hour manger cost × (1.5
hours + .75 hours + .5 hours + .25 hours)) +
($113.80 legal cost × (1.5 hours + .75 hours + .5
hours + .25 hours)) + $82.50 information tech cost
× (1.5 hours + .75 hours + .5 hours + .25 hours))/
4 = $147,225.
135 362 packers × ($39.69 per hour admin. cost ×
(4 hours + 2 hours + 1.33 hours + .67 hours)) +
($93.20 per hour manger cost × (1.5 hours + .75
hours + .5 hours + .25 hours)) + ($113.80 legal cost
× (1.5 hours + .75 hours + .5 hours + .25 hours))
+ ($82.50 information tech cost × (1.5 hours + .75
hours + .5 hours + .25 hours))/4 = $92,688.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
20:25 Sep 30, 2022
Jkt 259001
in § 201.306, and a statement of
severability among the provisions in
§ 201.390. The definitions in § 201.302
of a covered producer, market
vulnerable individual, livestock
producer, and regulated entity would
apply to proposed §§ 201.304 and
201.306, and the regulatory impacts of
the definitions are captured in the
regulatory impacts of §§ 201.304 and
201.306, which are highlighted in this
analysis.
The statement of severability in
proposed § 201.390 has no quantified
regulatory impact, as it only serves to
ensure that if any provision of
§ 201.302, § 201.304, or § 201.306 is
declared invalid or the applicability to
any person or circumstance is invalid,
the remainder of the provisions would
remain valid.
Proposed § 201.304 would provide
notice to the industry regarding unduly
prejudicial and discriminatory practices
that are prohibited and if they occur
would be a violation of sec. 202(a) of the
P&S Act. Practices that would be
prohibited as unduly prejudicial and
discriminatory under proposed
§ 201.304(a) include prejudice,
disadvantage, or discrimination that
otherwise inhibits market access to a
covered producer with respect to
livestock, poultry, meats, and meat food
products based on a covered producer’s
status as a market vulnerable individual
or as a cooperative. Examples of
prejudice or disadvantage are included
in proposed § 201.304(a)(3) and include
offering less favorable contract terms
than those generally offered, refusing to
deal, or adversely differential
performance, enforcement, or
termination of contracts.
Proposed § 201.304(b)(1) prohibits
retaliation or otherwise taking an
adverse action against a covered
producer because of the covered
producer’s participation in certain
activities described in § 201.304(b)(2).
Proposed § 201.304(b)(2)(i)-(vi) list
activities that are protected under
§ 201.304(b)(1). A covered producer that
communicates with a government
agency, or petitions a court, legislature,
or government agency for redress of
grievances is protected from retaliation
with respect to livestock, meats, meat
food products, livestock products in
unmanufactured form, or live poultry. A
covered producer who asserts rights
granted under the P&S Act, contract
rights, or rights to form or join a
producer or grower association to
collectively market livestock or poultry
would also be protected from
retaliation. Additionally, covered
producers would be protected from
retaliation if they communicate or
PO 00000
Frm 00029
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
60037
cooperate with a person for purposes of
improving production or marketing of
livestock or poultry, negotiate with a
regulated entity for purposes of
exploring a business relationship, or
support or participate as a witness in
any proceeding under the P&S Act or a
proceeding that relates to an alleged
violation of law by a regulated entity.
Proposed § 201.306(a) would provide
notice to the industry regarding specific
deceptive practices in which a regulated
entity may not engage with respect to
livestock, meats, meat food products,
livestock products in unmanufactured
form, or live poultry. Proposed
§ 201.306(b)-(e) would prohibit
deceptive practices in contract
formation, contract performance,
contract termination, and contract
refusal with respect to livestock and
meats and lists specific practices that
would constitute a violation of sec.
202(a) of the P&S Act. The prohibited
deceptive practices include making or
modifying a contract, performing under
or enforcing a contract, terminating a
contract, or refusing to contract with a
covered producer based on pretext,
omission of material facts, or false or
misleading statements.
Proposed § 201.390 would ensure that
if any provision of § 201.302, § 201.304,
or § 201.306 is declared invalid or the
applicability to any person or
circumstance is invalid, the remainder
of the provision would remain valid.
Protecting rights in contracting is an
important feature of both proposed
§§ 201.304 and 201.306. Proposed
§ 201.304 prohibits retaliation by
regulated entities through termination of
contracts, non-renewal of contracts,
refusing to deal, and interference in
farm real estate contracts as unduly
prejudicial and discriminatory
practices. Proposed § 201.306 prohibits
deceptive practices by regulated entities
in contracting with covered producers
including making or modifying a
contract, performing under or enforcing
a contract, terminating a contract, or
refusing to contract with a covered
producer based on pretext, false or
misleading statements, or omission of
material facts. A discussion of
contracting in these industries is,
therefore, useful in explaining the need
for these additional regulations. As will
be seen in the next three tables below
defining market shares of regulated
entities and the discussion that follows,
the unduly prejudicial, discriminatory,
and deceptive practices, including
retaliation, that proposed §§ 201.304
and 201.306 would prohibit are partially
attributable to the structure of the
livestock and poultry industries, the
imbalance of market power between
E:\FR\FM\03OCP3.SGM
03OCP3
60038
Federal Register / Vol. 87, No. 190 / Monday, October 3, 2022 / Proposed Rules
regulated entities, producers, growers,
and the potential market failure of
asymmetrical information, which, along
with imperfect competition, contributes
to hold-up.
Prevalence of Contracting in Cattle, Hog,
and Poultry Industries
Growing, production, and marketing
contracts feature prominently in the
livestock and poultry industries. As
outlined above, several provisions in
proposed §§ 201.304 and 201.306 would
affect the process of making, enforcing,
and terminating contracts for livestock,
poultry, and meat grown or marketed
under contract.
The type of contracting varies among
cattle, hogs, and poultry. Broilers, the
largest segment of poultry, are almost
exclusively grown under production
contracts, in which the live poultry
dealers, a regulated entity, own the
birds and provide poultry growers with
feed and medication to raise and care
for the birds until they reach the desired
market size. Poultry growers provide the
housing, the skill and efforts of labor,
water, electricity, fuel, and provide for
waste removal. Fed cattle marketing
contracts typically take the form of
marketing agreements as discussed
below. Hog production falls between
these two extremes.
As shown in the table below, over 96
percent of all broilers and over 42
percent of all hogs are grown under
contractual arrangements. Similar to
poultry contracts, swine contractors
typically own the slaughter hogs and
sell the finished hogs to pork packers.
The swine contractors typically provide
feed and medication to the swine
production contract growers who own
the growing facilities and provide
growing services. The following table
shows that the percentage of contract
growing arrangements by species has
remained relatively stable between 2007
and 2017.
TABLE 4—PERCENTAGE OF POULTRY AND HOG RAISED AND DELIVERED UNDER PRODUCTION CONTRACTS 136
Species
2007
Broilers .........................................................................................................................................
Turkeys ........................................................................................................................................
Hogs .............................................................................................................................................
Other types of contracts include
marketing agreements and forward
contracts. Under marketing agreements,
livestock producers market their
livestock to a packer for slaughter under
a verbal or written agreement. Under
forward contracts, producers and
packers agree to terms on a future sale
and purchase of livestock. These types
of agreements and contracts are
commonly referred to as Alternative
Marketing Arrangements (AMAs).
Pricing mechanisms vary across AMAs.
Some AMAs rely on a reported spot, or
negotiated, market price or exchangebased futures price for at least one
aspect of its price, while others involve
complicated pricing formulas with
premiums and discounts based on
carcass merits. The livestock producer
and packer agree on a pricing
mechanism under AMAs, but usually
not on a specific price.
AMS reports the number of cattle sold
to packers under formula, forward
contract, and negotiated pricing
mechanisms. The following table
illustrates the prevalence of contracting
in the marketing of fed cattle. Formula
pricing methods and forward contracts
are two forms of AMA contracts. Thus,
the first two columns in the following
2012
96.5
67.7
43.3
2017
96.4
68.5
43.5
96.3
69.5
42.4
table are cattle marketed under contract
and the third column represents the
spot market, or negotiated market, for
fed cattle including negotiated grid. The
data in the below table show that the
AMA contracting of cattle has increased
since 2010. Approximately 55 percent of
fed cattle were marketed under
contracts in 2010. By 2021, the
percentage of fed cattle marketed to
packers under AMA contracts had
increased to just over 72 percent. These
data also show the declines in the
percentage of cattle sold on the spot
market from 45.6 in 2010 to 27.6 in
2021.
TABLE 5—PERCENTAGE OF FED CATTLE SOLD BY TYPE OF PURCHASE 137
Year
lotter on DSK11XQN23PROD with PROPOSALS3
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
2017
2018
2019
2020
2021
Formula
.............................................................................................................................................
.............................................................................................................................................
.............................................................................................................................................
.............................................................................................................................................
.............................................................................................................................................
.............................................................................................................................................
.............................................................................................................................................
.............................................................................................................................................
.............................................................................................................................................
.............................................................................................................................................
.............................................................................................................................................
.............................................................................................................................................
44.9
48.4
54.7
60.0
58.1
58.2
58.2
58.7
62.0
65.7
64.1
61.5
Forward
contract
Negotiated
9.5
10.9
11.4
10.2
14.2
16.5
12.0
11.4
8.8
9.8
9.0
10.9
45.6
40.7
33.8
29.8
27.6
25.3
29.8
29.9
29.2
24.4
27.0
27.6
As previously discussed, and
illustrated in Table 4 above, over 40
percent of hogs are grown under
production contracts. These hogs are
then sold by swine contractors or to
other contract production growers to
packers under marketing contracts.
136 Agricultural Census, 2012 and 2017, available
at https://www.nass.usda.gov/Publications/
AgCensus/2017/Full_Report/Volume_1,_Chapter_1_
US/usv1.pdf (last accessed 8/9/2022).
137 U.S. Department of Agriculture, Agricultural
Marketing Service, available at: https://
mpr.datamart.ams.usda.gov/
menu.do?path=Products\Cattle\Weekly%20Cattle
(last accessed Aug. 2022).
VerDate Sep<11>2014
20:25 Sep 30, 2022
Jkt 259001
PO 00000
Frm 00030
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
E:\FR\FM\03OCP3.SGM
03OCP3
Federal Register / Vol. 87, No. 190 / Monday, October 3, 2022 / Proposed Rules
As can be seen in the below table, the
percentage of hogs sold under marketing
contracts has increased since 2010 to
over 98 percent in 2020. The spot
market for hogs has declined from 5.2
percent in 2010 to 1.5 percent in 2020.
60039
As these data demonstrate, almost all
hogs are marketed to packers under
some type of marketing contract.
TABLE 6—PERCENTAGE OF HOGS SOLD BY TYPE OF PURCHASE 138
Other marketing arrangements 139
Year
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
2017
2018
2019
2020
.............................................................................................................................................
.............................................................................................................................................
.............................................................................................................................................
.............................................................................................................................................
.............................................................................................................................................
.............................................................................................................................................
.............................................................................................................................................
.............................................................................................................................................
.............................................................................................................................................
.............................................................................................................................................
.............................................................................................................................................
lotter on DSK11XQN23PROD with PROPOSALS3
Structural Issues in the Cattle, Hog, and
Poultry Industries
The livestock and poultry industries
are characterized by a high volume of
growing, production, and marketing
contracts. High volume of this type of
contracting, coupled with high levels of
market concentration, may increase the
risk for anticompetitive behaviors of
undue prejudice and discrimination,
retaliation, and deception by regulated
entities, which can harm market
vulnerable producers.
Despite various policy and public
concerns with contracting, growing,
production, and marketing contracts can
offer certain benefits to the contracting
parties. Properly tailored, benefits can
include helping farmers, livestock
producers, and processors manage price
and production risks, elicit the
production of products with specific
quality attributes by tying prices to
those attributes, and facilitate the
smooth flow of commodities to
processing plants. Such attributes may
encourage certain efficiencies in use of
farm and processing capacities. Qualityrelated attributes and standards can
incentivize farmers to deliver products
that consumers desire and produce
products in ways that reduce processing
costs.141
138 U.S. Department of Agriculture, Agricultural
Marketing Service, available at: https://
mpr.datamart.ams.usda.gov/
menu.do?path=\Products (last accessed Aug. 2022).
139 Includes Packer Owned and Packer Sold, and
Other Purchase Arrangements.
140 Includes Swine Pork Market Formula, and
Other Market Formula.
141 RTI International, 2007, GIPSA Livestock and
Meat Marketing Study, Prepared for USDA, GIPSA;
Stephen R. Koontz, ‘‘Another Look at Alternative
Marketing Arrangement Use by the Cattle and Beef
Industry,’’ in Bart Fischer et al., ‘‘The U.S. Beef
Supply Chain: Issues and Challenges Proceedings of
a Workshop on Cattle Markets,’’ 2021. But see C.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
20:25 Sep 30, 2022
Jkt 259001
There are, however, trade-offs with
the use of these contracts. In
concentrated industries, like the cattle,
hog, and poultry industries, where
market power is present, these types of
contracts may result in increased
opportunities for undue prejudices and
discrimination, retaliation, and
deception, among other concerns, which
cause inefficiencies in the markets for
livestock, poultry, and meat.142
Heightened market concentration
implies that livestock producers and
poultry growers face fewer marketing
and contract options compared to less
concentrated markets. Livestock
producers and poultry growers may find
themselves in a take-it-or-leave it
situation when a new or renewal
contract is presented due to a limited
number of packers and live poultry
dealers with which to contract. Thus,
livestock producers and poultry dealers
entering into new or renewal contracts
may be taken advantage of through
discriminatory, deceptive, or retaliatory
practices.
Robert Taylor, ‘‘Market Structure of the Livestock
Industry,’’ Testimony before the House Committee
of Agriculture, April 16, 2007, available at https://
www.iatp.org/documents/c-robert-taylor-testimonymarket-structure-of-the-livestock-industry; C. Robert
Taylor, ‘‘Harvested Cattle, Slaughtered Markets,’’
April 27, 2022, available at https://www.antitrust
institute.org/work-product/aai-advisor-roberttaylor-issues-new-analysis-on-the-market-powerproblem-in-beef-lays-out-new-policy-framework-forensuring-competition-and-fairness-in-cattle-andbeef-markets/(contesting quality incentives
delivered through these agreements).
142 Nathan H. Miller, et al., ‘‘Buyer Power in the
Beef Packing Industry: An Update on Research in
Progress,’’ April 13, 2022, available at https://
www.nathanhmiller.org/cattlemarkets.pdf. See also
Michael Kades, ‘‘Protecting Livestock Producers
and Chicken Growers,’’ Washington Center for
Equitable Growth (May 5, 2022), available at https://
equitablegrowth.org/research-paper/protectinglivestock-producers-and-chicken-growers/.
PO 00000
Frm 00031
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
45.4
47.6
47.7
48.3
45.9
46.0
50.0
52.5
56.5
59.8
61.3
Formula 140
49.4
48.2
48.6
48.4
51.4
51.4
47.6
45.0
41.3
38.4
37.1
Negotiated
5.2
4.2
3.6
3.2
2.7
2.6
2.5
2.5
2.2
1.8
1.5
Livestock and poultry contracts may
hold producers and growers captive,
due to limited number of packers and
live poultry dealers and therefore
susceptible to unjust, prejudicial and
retaliatory practices. For example, a
contract that limits a poultry grower’s
services to a single integrator, even if
the contract provides for fair
compensation to the grower, still leaves
the grower subject to retaliation risks.
The grower may face the hold-up risk
that the contractor may require
additional capital investments or may
face retaliation, when the contractor
imposes lower returns at the time of
contract renewal.143 Some growers make
substantial long-term capital
investments as part of livestock or
poultry production contracts, including
land, poultry or hog houses, and
equipment. Those investments may tie
the grower to a single contractor or
integrator, furthering the indebtedness,
and thus also imbalance of power.
In the poultry industry, limited
integrator choice may accentuate
contract risks. The data in Table 3 above
show that 52 percent of broiler growers,
accounting for 56 percent of total
production, report having only one or
two integrators in their local areas. Even
where multiple growers are present,
there are high costs to switching, owing
to the differences in technical
specifications that integrators require.
The growers likely need to invest in
new equipment and learn to apply
different operational techniques due to
different breeds, target weights and
grow-out cycles.
143 See Vukina and Leegomonchai, ‘‘Oligopsony
Power, Asset Specificity, and Hold-Up: Evidence
From The Broiler Industry,’’ American Journal of
Agricultural Economics, 88(3): 589–605 (August
2006).
E:\FR\FM\03OCP3.SGM
03OCP3
60040
Federal Register / Vol. 87, No. 190 / Monday, October 3, 2022 / Proposed Rules
lotter on DSK11XQN23PROD with PROPOSALS3
In 2013, production contracts covered
$58 billion in agricultural production,
83 percent of which was poultry and
hog contracts.144 Most hogs are
produced and marketed under
production and marketing contracts.
Open market negotiated trade
represented 9 percent of total trades for
hogs in 2008 and dropped to 2 percent
in 2020.145 In effect, the only
production/marketing choice for a hog
producer is to enter a contract.
In the cattle sector, cow-calf
operations incur a significant
investment in breeding stock and
typically sell steers and heifers once a
year. Price risk can therefore rise from
the months-long production process.146
Access to competitive markets, absent
from discrimination, undue prejudice,
and retaliation, is important to the
economic livelihood of vulnerable
producers. Reduced marketing
options—fewer options to sell on the
spot market, or lack of access to
contracts—can leave producers
susceptible to unfair trade practices.
Spot market trades, or negotiated trades,
as opposed to marketing agreements or
contracts, for fed cattle accounted for 51
percent of all trades in 2008 and fell to
27 percent in 2020.147
A 2006 survey indicated that growers
with access to a single integrator
received 7 to 8 percent less
compensation, on average, than farmers
located in areas with 4 or more
integrators.148 If live poultry dealers
already possess some market power to
reduce prices for poultry growing
services, some contracts can extend that
power by raising the costs of entry for
new competitors or allowing for price
discrimination.149
144 MacDonald, J.M. ‘‘Trends in Agricultural
Contracts.’’ Choices. 2015. Quarter 3. Available at
https://www.choicesmagazine.org/choicesmagazine/theme-articles/current-issues-inagricultural-contracts/trends-in-agriculturalcontracts, accessed 9–19–22.
145 USDA, AMS, FTPP, Packers and Stockyards
Division. Packer Annual Reports, 2021 and 2012.
Available at https://www.ams.usda.gov/reports/psdannual-reports, accessed 9–19–22.
146 Martinez, C.C., Maples, J.G. and Benavidez, J.
Beef Cattle Markets and COVID–19. Applied
Economics Perspectives and Policy, (2021) 43: 304–
314. Available at https://doi.org/10.1002/
aepp.13080, accessed 9/19/22.
147 USDA, AMS, FTPP, Packers and Stockyards
Division. Packer Annual Reports, 2021 and 2012.
Available at https://www.ams.usda.gov/reports/psdannual-reports, accessed 9–19–22.
148 MacDonald, J. and N. Key. ‘‘Market Power in
Poultry Production Contracting? Evidence from a
Farm Survey.’’ Journal of Agricultural and Applied
Economics. 44(4) (November 2012): 477–490.
149 See, e.g., Williamson, Oliver E. ‘‘Markets and
Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications,’’
New York: The Free Press (1975); Edlin, Aaron S.
& Stefan Reichelstein (1996) ‘‘Holdups, Standard
Breach Remedies, and Optimal Investment,’’ The
VerDate Sep<11>2014
20:25 Sep 30, 2022
Jkt 259001
Asymmetric Information
There is asymmetry in the
information available to livestock
producers and livestock and poultry
growers and the packers, swine
contractors, and live poultry dealers
with whom they contract. The larger
packers, swine contractors, and live
poultry dealers generally have more
information (costs of production, input
quality, and consumer demand, for
example) that is useful in contracting
than the smaller livestock producers
and livestock and poultry growers. This
asymmetry of information can lead to
deceptive practices by regulated entities
with superior information in making or
modifying production, marketing, or
growing contracts, performing under,
enforcing, or terminating these
contracts, or refusing to contract with a
covered producer based on pretext,
omission of information, or false or
misleading statements.
Some marketing contracts for fed
cattle, for example, use various plant
averages in the calculation for the base
price of the cattle in the marketing
contract. Only the packer has the
information about the plant averages
and producers cannot independently
verify the information. Similar issues
exist in hog marketing contracts. For
contracts based on the pork cutout, the
hog packer has more information about
the direct retail pork demand and hence
pork cutout prices than hog sellers.
Asymmetric information is
particularly acute in all contracts
between poultry growers and live
poultry dealers. Live poultry dealers
hold information on how individual
poultry growers perform under a variety
of contracts. The average number of
contracts for the live poultry dealers
filing annual reports with AMS in 2020
was 251. The largest live poultry dealers
contracted with several thousand
growers.151 Most growers producing
poultry under production contracts are
paid under a poultry grower ranking or
‘‘tournament’’ pay system. Under
tournament systems, the contract
between the poultry grower and the
company for whom the grower raises
poultry for slaughter pays the grower
based on a grouping, ranking, or
comparison of poultry growers
delivering poultry to the same company
during a specified period. Generally,
live poultry dealers provide most of the
inputs to all the growers in each poultry
tournament used to determine grower
pay. In these tournaments, the live
poultry dealers have information about
the quality of the inputs, while each
grower only knows what he or she can
observe. Due to a lack of scales and tools
to evaluate feed quality, a grower may
not be able to weigh, measure or
evaluate the inputs it received such as
chicks and feed, and he or she almost
American Economic Review 86(3): 478- 501 (June
1996).
150 For additional discussion see MacDonald, J.M.
2016 ‘‘Concentration, contracting, and competition
policy in U.S. agribusiness,’’ Competition Law
Review, No. 1–2016: 3–8.
151 All live poultry dealers are required to
annually file PSD form 3002 ‘‘Annual Report of
Live Poultry Dealers,’’ OMB control number 0581–
0308. The annual report form is available to public
on the internet at https://www.ams.usda.gov/sites/
default/files/media/PSP3002.pdf.
One indication of potential market
power is industry concentration.150
Table 2 presented earlier, shows the
level of concentration in the livestock
and poultry slaughtering industries for
2010–2020. The table shows the
combined market share of the four
largest steer and heifer slaughterers
remained stable between 83 and 85
percent from 2010 to 2019 and dropped
to 81 percent in 2020. Four-firm
concentration ratios for hog and broiler
slaughter has also remained relatively
stable between 62 and 70 percent and 51
and 54 percent, respectively.
As discussed previously, the data in
Table 2 are estimates of national fourfirm concentration ratios at the national
level, but the relevant economic markets
for livestock and poultry may be
regional or local, and concentration in
the relevant market may be higher than
the national level. For example, while
poultry markets may appear to be the
least concentrated in terms of the fourfirm concentration ratios presented
above, relevant economic markets for
poultry growing services are more
localized than markets for fed cattle or
hogs, and local concentration in poultry
markets is often greater than in hog and
other livestock markets. The data
presented earlier in Table 3 highlights
this issue by showing the limited ability
a poultry grower has to switch to a
different integrator. As a result, national
concentration may not demonstrate
accurately the options poultry growers
in a particular region face.
The levels of industry concentration
shown in Tables 2 and 3 may contribute
to oligopolistic market power and
asymmetric information. The result is
that the contracts bargained between the
parties may leave livestock producers,
swine production contract growers, and
poultry growers vulnerable to
detrimental risks of anticompetitive
conduct such as prejudice and
discrimination, retaliation, and
deception due to the structural issues
discussed above and may result in
inefficiencies in the marketplace.
PO 00000
Frm 00032
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
E:\FR\FM\03OCP3.SGM
03OCP3
Federal Register / Vol. 87, No. 190 / Monday, October 3, 2022 / Proposed Rules
certainly will not know about the inputs
received by other growers. Live poultry
dealers also have historical information
concerning growers’ production and
income under many different
circumstances for all the growers with
which it contracts, while an individual
grower, like most other producers, only
has information concerning his or her
own production and income.
Prohibiting deception may serve to
reduce the negative impacts from
asymmetric information. Prohibiting
retaliation against producers or growers
because they joined a cooperative or
association, shared information to
improve their production or growing
practices, or communicated with the
government should lead to reducing the
information asymmetry between
regulated entities and producers and
growers.
lotter on DSK11XQN23PROD with PROPOSALS3
Hold-Up Risk
Hold-up is another risk that is
particularly acute in the service
contracts between poultry growers and
live poultry dealers. Hold-up is far less
of a risk for hog and cattle producers, so
the discussion here is limited to poultry
growing to highlight this risk to poultry
growers. Substantial gaps exist between
the periods of time covered by the
contract and the mortgage on poultry
housing, creating uncertainty around
whether growers will be able to repay
their debt and recoup their investments,
introducing hold-up risk into the
contracting process. As discussed in the
preamble, hold-up is the risk growers
face at the time of contract renewal
when integrators make contract renewal
dependent on further grower
investments not disclosed at the time of
the original agreements.152
This is of concern in poultry
production contracts because the capital
requirements related to growing
chickens are significant and highly
specialized (that is, they have little
value outside of growing chickens). As
a result, growers entering the market are
tied to growing chickens to pay off the
financing of the capital investment.
Growers have reported that they must
accept unfavorable contract terms or
endure unfavorable treatment during a
contract—including inappropriate limits
on their ability to form associations,
assert their rights under the law or
contract (such as viewing the weighing
of broilers), communicate with
government entities, and seek
alternative business relationships—
152 Vukina, Tom, and Porametr Leegomonchai.
‘‘Oligopsony Power, Asset Specificity, and HoldUp: Evidence from the Broiler Industry.’’ American
Journal of Agricultural Economics 88 (2006).
VerDate Sep<11>2014
20:25 Sep 30, 2022
Jkt 259001
because they are tied to production to
pay off lenders and they have few, if
any, alternative integrators with whom
they can contract. Hog producers which
invest heavily in production facilities
face may similar risks.
Long term, this behavior may result in
underinvestment in production, which
is inefficient. Alternatively, if growers
do not anticipate hold-up, then growers
may spend too much on investments
because the integrator who demands
them is not incurring any cost. The
resulting over-investment in capital by
those growers facing hold-up is also
inefficient. Hold-up risk is a
manifestation of both market power and
asymmetric information.
Hold-up risk can be alleviated with a
prohibition on retaliation for certain
protected activities that enhance the
competitive environment and market
integrity, as well as a prohibition on
deception and the accompanying
reduction in asymmetric information.
Increased information to growers by
allowing growers to freely communicate
and share information without fear of
retaliation would allow growers to be
make more informed decision about the
efficient level of capital in which to
invest.
Contracting, Industry Structure, and
Market Failure: Summary of the Need
for Regulation
Growing, production, and marketing
contracts benefit the livestock and
poultry industries. Existing structural
issues may result in imperfect
competition, risks of undue prejudice
and discrimination, retaliation,
deception, unequal bargaining power,
and information asymmetries,
potentially increasing hold-up risk.
USDA’s long-standing policy has been
that the P&S Act prohibits the type of
conduct that this proposed rule
addresses.153 Sections 201.304 and
201.306 will serve to fill-in gaps where
other Federal and state statutes, not
specific to the agricultural sector,
overlap and fail to provide full
protections. Proposed § 201.304 would
prohibit packers, swine contractors, and
live poultry dealers from unduly
153 Agricultural Marketing Service, USDA,
‘‘Undue and Unreasonable Preferences and
Advantages Under the Packers and Stockyards
Act,’’ Final Rule, December 11, 2020, 85 FR 79779,
79787, available at https://www.federalregister.gov/
documents/2020/12/11/2020-27117/undue-andunreasonable-preferences-and-advantages-underthe-packers-and-stockyards-act; Agricultural
Marketing Service, USDA, ‘‘Frequently Asked
Questions on the Enforcement of Undue and
Unreasonable Preferences under the Packers and
Stockyards Act,’’ August 2021, available at https://
www.ams.usda.gov/rules-regulations/packers-andstockyards-act/faq (last accessed Aug. 2022).
PO 00000
Frm 00033
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
60041
discriminating and employing undue
prejudices against market vulnerable
producers and cooperatives.
Proposed § 201.304 would also
prohibit retaliation including
termination of contracts, refusing to
deal, refusing to renew a contract, and
interference in farm real estate
transactions or contracts with third
parties. Retaliation would only be
effective if producers and growers had
a small number of packers and live
poultry dealers to market their livestock
or growing services. If producers and
growers had lots of choices among
packers and live poultry dealers,
producers and growers would simply
market their livestock or growing
services to a different packer or live
poultry dealer if they were being
retaliated against. Thus, retaliation is
more likely to occur in markets with
imperfect competition and an
oligopsonistic structure, such as the
cattle, hog, and poultry markets. This
clear statement regarding prohibitions
on retaliation could reduce instances of
retaliation against livestock producers
and livestock and poultry growers.
Proposed § 201.304 would also
protect various activities that would
allow covered producers to freely
communicate with each other and
governmental entities. To establish a
climate of compliance, regulated entities
would be required to maintain all
relevant records in compliance with
proposed § 201.304.
Proposed § 201.306 would prohibit
packers, swine contractors, and live
poultry dealers from employing
deceptive practices against producers
and growers in forming, performing, and
terminating contracts and refusing to
contract based on false or misleading
information.
By setting forth specific prohibitions
on unduly prejudicial and
discriminatory and deceptive practices,
the proposed rule would reinforce
producers’ and growers’ existing rights
to gather and share information, while
reducing the fear of retaliation and
interference in the contracting process.
The prohibitions in the proposed rule
would also continue to support, and
possibly promote more efficient and
equitable reducing information
asymmetries and hold-up risk, reducing
retaliation, pretext, false and misleading
information, and increasing
communication, cooperation, and
retention of legal rights. The
prohibitions specified in proposed
§§ 201.304 and 201.306 would
ultimately assist in mitigating the
impacts of imperfect competition.
E:\FR\FM\03OCP3.SGM
03OCP3
60042
Federal Register / Vol. 87, No. 190 / Monday, October 3, 2022 / Proposed Rules
Cost-Benefit Analysis of Proposed
§§ 201.304 and 201.306
Regulatory Alternatives Considered
Executive Order 12866 requires an
assessment of costs and benefits of
potentially effective and reasonably
feasible alternatives to the planned
regulations and an explanation of why
the planned regulatory action is
preferable to the potential
alternatives.154 AMS considered three
regulatory alternatives. The first
alternative that AMS considered is to
maintain the status quo and not propose
§§ 201.304 and 201.306. The second
alternative that AMS considered is to
issue proposed §§ 201.304 and 201.306
as presented in this proposed rule.155
This second alternative is AMS’s
preferred alternative as will be
explained below. The third alternative
that AMS considered is proposing
§§ 201.304 and 201.306, but exempting
small businesses, as defined by the
Small Business Administration (SBA),
from having to comply with the
recordkeeping requirement of
§ 201.304(c).
Regulatory Alternative 1: Status Quo
Alternative
If proposed §§ 201.304 and 201.306
are never promulgated, there are no
marginal costs and marginal benefits as
industry participants will not alter their
conduct. From a cost standpoint, this
Status Quo Alternative is the least-cost
alternative compared to the other two
alternatives. This alternative also has no
marginal benefits. Since there are no
changes from the status quo under this
regulatory alternative, it will serve as
the baseline against which to measure
the other two alternatives.
lotter on DSK11XQN23PROD with PROPOSALS3
Regulatory Alternative 2: The Proposed
Alternative
As discussed above, proposed
§ 201.304 prohibits undue prejudice,
discrimination, and retaliation by
regulated entities and adds a
requirement for regulated entities to
maintain records, for a period of five
years, related to its compliance with
proposed § 201.304. Proposed § 201.306
would prohibit deceptive practices by
regulated entities in contracting with
covered producers including making or
154 See Section 6(a)(3)(C) of Executive Order
12866.
155 This proposed rule includes § 201.302, which
defines a covered producer, livestock producer, and
regulated entity. These definitions would apply to
proposed §§ 201.304 and 201.306. The definitions
proposed in § 201.302 are captured in the regulatory
impacts of proposed §§ 201.304 and 201.306. The
proposed rule also includes § 201.390 which states
all provisions are severable in case any provision
is declared invalid. Proposed § 201.390
VerDate Sep<11>2014
20:25 Sep 30, 2022
Jkt 259001
modifying a contract, performing under
or enforcing a contract, terminating a
contract, or refusing to contract with a
covered producer based on pretext,
omission of information, or false or
misleading statements.
Regulatory Alternative 2: Benefits of the
Proposed Alternative
Reductions in prejudicial,
discriminatory, retaliatory, and
deceptive practices by packers, swine
contractors, and live poultry dealers
would benefit livestock and poultry
producers and growers. These types of
anticompetitive conduct do not have
procompetitive benefits and are
generally conduct that occurs outside of
written contracts. Retaliation, for
example, is not written into a contract,
but can occur by a packer terminating a
contract based on pretext if a livestock
producer takes an action for which a
packer disapproves, such as joining a
producer group that the packer
denounces. There need not be any
changes to the contracting process or
changes in the use of marketing,
production, or growing arrangements for
producers and growers to receive
benefits. Any reductions in prejudicial,
discriminatory, retaliatory, and
deceptive practices by packers, swine
contractors, and live poultry dealers
would benefits producers and growers.
The amount of benefits that would be
received by producers and growers
depends on the extent to which the
proposed rule reduces prejudicial,
discriminatory, retaliatory, and
deceptive practices. That, in turn, is
bounded by the degree to which any of
these types of activities are occurring in
the baseline. The following discussion
is about the types of benefits that
producers and growers would receive
from a reduction in prejudicial,
discriminatory, retaliatory, and
deceptive practices by packers, swine
contractors, and live poultry dealers. If
the reductions are small, the benefits
would be small. The greater the
reductions, the greater the potential
benefits.
AMS discusses the potential benefits
to livestock producers and growers from
the Proposed Alternative (proposed
§§ 201.304 and 201.306) compared to
the Status Quo Alternative. USDA’s
long-standing policy has been that the
P&S Act prohibits the type of conduct
that the Proposed Alternative (proposed
§§ 201.304 and 201.306) addresses. The
Proposed Alternative adds specificity to
deceptive, unjustly discriminatory
practices (retaliation), and unreasonable
prejudices. Consequently, AMS expects
packers, live poultry dealers, and swine
contractors would review the proposed
PO 00000
Frm 00034
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
rule and assess compliance of their
contracts and conduct with the
proposed rule. Some packers, swine
contractors, and live poultry dealers
may make some minor modifications if
they believe their contracts or conduct
are not in compliance. AMS expects all
regulated entities to maintain relevant
records relating to their compliance
with proposed § 201.304, which would
provide further benefits to the industry.
The size of the benefits is difficult to
quantify as they depend on the amount
of undue prejudice, discrimination, and
deception that will be avoided should
the provisions in the Proposed
Alternative be adopted by the Agency.
The more undue prejudice,
discrimination, and deception that will
be avoided, the larger the benefits. AMS
is unable to quantify the benefits and
will present a qualitative discussion of
the types of potential benefits that
accrue from reductions in prejudice,
discrimination, retaliation, and
deception.
The following discussion is for the
benefits, in general, to the livestock and
poultry industries from the provisions
in the Proposed Alternative, and similar
provisions that USDA has long viewed
as violations of P&S Act. The added
benefits to the industry from the
Proposed Alternative over the Status
Quo Alternative occur when packers,
swine contractors, and live poultry
dealers alter their contracts and/or
conduct of their employees to reduce
instances of deceptive, prejudicial, and
discriminatory practices, including
retaliation, and keep records about their
compliance programs. The potential
benefits include protecting producer
and grower rights, improved corporate
culture and the ability to investigate
compliance through recordkeeping
requirement, addressing asymmetric
information, prohibiting deceptive
practices, and other benefits.
Protecting Producer and Grower Rights
Concentration and lack of competition
in livestock procurement markets and
poultry contracting can lead to abuses of
market power such as undue prejudice
and discrimination, retaliation,
deception, fraud, and restrictions of
producer and grower rights. A key
purpose of specifying certain
prohibitions on unduly prejudicial,
discriminatory, and deceptive practices,
including those in the Proposed
Alternative, is to protect livestock
producers, swine contractors and
poultry growers’ rights under the P&S
Act. The Proposed Alternative would
also help protect producers and growers
from unfair and deceptive practices
stemming from market power
E:\FR\FM\03OCP3.SGM
03OCP3
lotter on DSK11XQN23PROD with PROPOSALS3
Federal Register / Vol. 87, No. 190 / Monday, October 3, 2022 / Proposed Rules
imbalances such as undue prejudice,
discrimination, retaliation, and
deception by using pretext and false and
misleading information in contracting
by packers and live poultry dealers.
These benefits of prohibiting
prejudicial, discriminatory, and
deceptive practices, including those in
the proposed rule, would accrue not
only to the market’s vulnerable and
cooperative producers and growers who
have been subjected to the prohibited
practices, but also to those for whom the
proposed rule’s deterrence effects would
protect from future potential abuses.
For example, proposed
§ 201.304(a)(1) and (2) in the Proposed
Alternative would prohibit undue
prejudice and discrimination by
packers, swine contractors, and live
poultry dealers against market
vulnerable producers and growers and
cooperatives. This prohibition would
protect vulnerable producers and
growers and cooperatives who would
potentially face these types of
discrimination. Proposed
§ 201.304(a)(3) in the Proposed
Alternative includes examples of
unduly prejudicial and discriminatory
conduct, including termination of
contracts, refusing to deal, and
interference in farm real estate
transactions or contracts with third
parties. Unfair termination of contracts
and refusal to deal can lead to an
inefficient allocation of resources.
Proposed § 201.304(b)(1) in the
Proposed Alternative would prohibit
packers, swine contractors, and live
poultry dealers from retaliating against
producers and growers for engaging in
certain protected activities.
Additionally, proposed § 201.304(b)(2)
would protect producers and growers
from retaliation by regulated entities for
engaging in various activities, including
communicating with a government
agency, seeking redress before a court,
or asserting rights to join a producer or
grower association, collectively process
and market livestock or poultry, or
supporting or participating as a witness
in any proceeding under the P&S Act, or
a proceeding that relates to an alleged
violation of law by a regulated entity.
These provisions would also protect
producers and growers from retaliation
resulting from communication or
cooperating with a person to improve
the production of livestock or poultry
and from communicating with a
regulated entity to explore a business
relationship. These types of protections
can improve market efficiency.
The Proposed Alternative’s § 201.306
would add a prohibition on packers,
swine contractors, and live poultry
dealers of committing the deceptive
VerDate Sep<11>2014
20:25 Sep 30, 2022
Jkt 259001
practices of pretext, providing false and
misleading information, or omission of
material facts in forming, performing,
and terminating contracts and refusing
to contract with producers and growers
with respect to livestock poultry and
meat. Prohibitions on deception could
also improve efficiency by reducing
instances where resources are allocated
based on pretext, false or misleading
information, or omission of material
facts. That is, incorrect or incomplete
information can misguide the allocation
of resources such as land, labor, and
capital away from their best use. The
benefits of a more efficient allocation of
resources from these types of
prohibitions would be captured by
producers, growers, packers, and live
poultry dealers. These types of benefits
would be directly related to the
reduction in prejudicial, discriminatory,
retaliatory, and deceptive practices.
These proposed provisions would
further promote integrity in the market
and should give current and prospective
producers and growers more confidence
that they would be treated fairly.
Recordkeeping
There are multiple potential benefits
of the record-keeping provision in the
Proposed Alternative’s proposed
§ 201.304(c). Record-keeping regulations
can reduce AMS investigative costs and
improve the quality of the
investigations. Access to essential
records would improve AMS
enforcement and assist AMS in
assessing the effectiveness of the
regulated entity’s compliance with
proposed § 201.304(c). Information that
AMS would gather when conducting
compliance reviews, can enable AMS to
promote market competitiveness and
efficiency, as well as protect market
participants against discrimination and
other abusive practices. The rights of
vulnerable producers and cooperatives
can be better upheld when records of
regulated entities are maintained and
can be reviewed by AMS.
Another potential benefit of the
recordkeeping requirement in the
Proposed Alternative’s § 201.304(c) is
that regulated entities would know that
AMS may be able to obtain and review
records during investigations. This may
result in a change in corporate culture
of regulated entities in favor of
increased voluntary compliance with
proposed § 201.304 and reductions in
undue prejudice, discrimination, and
retaliation because regulated entities
would know their records can be
reviewed. Company leaders may shift
the corporate culture in order to comply
with the proposed rule.
PO 00000
Frm 00035
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
60043
Addressing Asymmetric Information
Several provisions in the Proposed
Alternative would enhance the
protection of the rights of producers and
growers to lawfully communicate and to
associate with others to explore
business relationships and improve
production practices and in the
marketing of livestock, poultry, and
meat. These provisions would benefit
producers and growers by encouraging
the use of their currently existing legal
rights to cooperate that would solidify
and enhance their access to information.
This in turn, would help address
information asymmetry and thus help
producers and growers make better
business decisions, enhance their
competitiveness, reduce hold-up risk,
and promote innovation and economic
efficiency in the industry.
The Proposed Alternative, by
protecting the rights of growers and
producers to form associations and
communicate freely with one another
and to communicate with other
regulated entities for the purpose of
exploring a business relationship,
would help close this information gap.
This would benefit producers and
growers by improving industry
transparency, enhancing the bargaining
power of supplier groups if they elect to
organize in such a way.
This proposed rule would prohibit
retaliation against covered producers
due to their association with other
producers and regulated entities, which
could increase the information available
to growers that is important in decision
making. Improved safeguarding of
protected activities may enable the
producer or grower to improve business
decision-making and manage risk,
including potentially acquiring external
insurance and risk-management
products. In addition, facilitating
producers and growers’ ability to gain
more and better information would help
correct information asymmetry and
improve transparency and completeness
in contracts.
More information would also reduce
the risks associated with hold-up as
discussed above. By protecting rights to
freely communicate and associate, this
proposed rule would facilitate
communication across the industry that
may help disseminate information
regarding new innovations and best
practices within the industry. These
types of provisions that could provide
producers and growers with access to
more and better information should
promote innovation and economic
efficiency in the industry.
The Proposed Alternative may also
serve to reduce the risk of violating sec.
E:\FR\FM\03OCP3.SGM
03OCP3
60044
Federal Register / Vol. 87, No. 190 / Monday, October 3, 2022 / Proposed Rules
202(a) of the P&S Act because it would
provide clarification to the livestock and
poultry industries as to the
discriminatory and deceptive practices
that would be prohibited under that
section of the Act. Less risk through the
clarification provided in the Proposed
Alternative would likely foster fairness
in contracting by providing explicit
protections for livestock producers,
swine production contract growers, and
poultry growers.
lotter on DSK11XQN23PROD with PROPOSALS3
Prohibiting Deceptive Practices
Proposed Alternative’s § 201.306
specifies prohibited practices that
would be considered deceptive, and
thus in violation of sec. 202(a) of the
P&S Act. Though USDA already protects
producers and growers from deceptive
practices, the proposed rule would
explicitly protect suppliers from
deception by packers and live poultry
dealers from pretextual justifications,
providing false and misleading
information, and the omission of
material facts in contracting. Prohibited
deceptions, including false statements,
pretext, or omissions, can prevent or
mislead producers and growers, sellers,
or buyers from making informed
decisions and thus represents a market
inefficiency. The provisions in the
Proposed Alternative would help give
producers and growers confidence that
the information provided by processors
is reliable, which would help them to
make better and more informed business
decisions and manage risk.
Other Benefits
While some of these protections
already benefit individual producers
and growers, ensuring they cover the
full marketplace and can be enforced
individually adds to the overall integrity
and fairness of livestock and poultry
contracting. Specifying these
protections may bring additional
benefits above the Status Quo
Alternative.
Growing, production, and marketing
contracting has many benefits in the
livestock and poultry industries. The
Proposed Alternative can further
enhance the documented benefits of
contracting by prohibiting unduly
prejudicial, discriminatory, and
deceptive practices. Packers, swine
contractors, and live poultry dealers
have at times exploited their market
power through business practices that
have unjustly harmed producers and
livestock and poultry growers. These
abuses have led to a climate of fear
among producers and growers that
certain actions they might undertake
such as communication with
government or other regulated entities
VerDate Sep<11>2014
20:25 Sep 30, 2022
Jkt 259001
to pursue business relationships,
association with certain groups, or
making lawful public complaints about
the packers, swine contractors, or live
poultry dealers might result in harmful
retaliations. AMS intends the Proposed
Alternative to promote integrity to the
marketplace by enhancing the
protection of the rights of the producers
and growers and alleviating those fears.
The literature and data on these topics
are not sufficient to allow AMS to
estimate the magnitude of the
inefficiencies that the Proposed
Alternative may correct above the Status
Quo Alternative, nor the degree to
which the additional producer and
grower protections would address
inefficiencies. Though AMS is unable to
quantify the benefits of the proposed
regulation, this analysis has explained
the types of benefits that would be
derived from reductions in prejudice,
discrimination, retaliation, and
deception. If the reductions are small,
the benefits would be small. The greater
the reductions, the greater the potential
benefits.
Regulatory Alternative 2: Costs of the
Proposed Alternative
Under the Proposed Alternative, the
proposed rule would not impose any
restrictions on numbers or types of
production or marketing contracts that
can be utilized, use of AMAs,
tournaments, or base price mechanisms
in contracts for packers, swine
contractors, and live poultry dealers.
Instead, the Proposed Alternative
enhances the prohibited unduly
prejudicial, unjustly discriminatory, and
deceptive practices that AMS already
considers violations of secs. 202(a) and
202(b) of the P&S Act. AMS does not
expect the Proposed Alternative’s
§§ 201.304 and 201.306 to result in any
measurable indirect costs resulting from
adjustments by the livestock and
poultry industries to reduce their use of
AMAs, poultry tournaments, pricing
mechanisms, or to result in a significant
number of substantial changes to
existing marketing or production
contracts. Nor does AMS expect the
Proposed Alternative’s §§ 201.304 and
201.306 to have any material effect on
the quantity of meat or poultry
produced.
Litigation Costs
AMS expects the Proposed
Alternative’s §§ 201.304 and 201.306 to
reduce litigation. The Proposed
Alternative clarifies the prohibited
unduly prejudicial, discriminatory, and
deceptive practices that would violate
sec. 202(a) of the P&S Act. The
clarification could result in a reduction
PO 00000
Frm 00036
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
in litigation costs if companies come
into compliance without any
enforcement action. This regulation
encourages regulated entities to
proactively avoid prejudicial,
discriminatory, and deceptive practices
that could otherwise lead to costly
litigation. Further, some firms may
develop policies and procedures to
comply with the proposed
recordkeeping requirements. This effect
could reduce litigation and thus result
in reduced litigation costs for regulated
entities.
However, there are several provisions
in the Proposed Alternative’s § 201.304
that could result in additional litigation.
AMS has received formal and informal
complaints against packers, swine
contractors, and live poultry dealers for
retaliation for belonging to various
producer and grower associations,
contacting AMS to file a complaint,
asserting legal rights, and contacting a
competing regulated entity to pursue a
contractual relationship. Similarly,
there are several provisions in the
Proposed Alternative’s § 201.306 that
could result in additional litigation,
including refusals by regulated entities
to enter into or renegotiate contracts and
contract terminations by producers and
growers. The clarity of the practices that
AMS considers to be discriminatory and
deceptive in the Proposed Alternative’s
§§ 201.304 and 201.306 could offer
producers and growers new hope for
relief from courts for perceived undue
prejudicial, discriminatory, and
deceptive practices by regulated
entities. This effect could result in
increased litigation.
AMS is uncertain as to which effect
will dominate and to what extent. Given
both effects, AMS does not expect large
increases or decreases in litigation from
the proposed rule and, therefore, does
not estimate litigation costs in this
analysis.
Direct Costs of the Proposed Option
AMS expects the Proposed
Alternative’s §§ 201.304 and 201.306
would only result in direct
administrative and recordkeeping costs
to the industry. AMS expects that
packers, swine contractors, and live
poultry dealers would incur direct
administrative costs of learning the
proposed rule and then reviewing and,
if necessary, revising marketing and
production contracts to ensure
compliance with the Proposed
Alternative’s §§ 201.304 and 201.306.
Regulated entities would also incur
recordkeeping costs from keeping the
records required under the Proposed
Alternative’s § 201.304. The expected
total costs of the Proposed Alternative’s
E:\FR\FM\03OCP3.SGM
03OCP3
Federal Register / Vol. 87, No. 190 / Monday, October 3, 2022 / Proposed Rules
§§ 201.304 and 201.306 will be the
direct administrative costs and
recordkeeping costs of that regulatory
alternative. The direct administrative
costs and recordkeeping costs will be
estimated below.
lotter on DSK11XQN23PROD with PROPOSALS3
Direct Administrative Costs
AMS expects that the Proposed
Alternative’s §§ 201.304 and 201.306
would prompt packers, live poultry
dealers, and swine contractors to first
review and learn the proposed rule and
then review their procurement policies
and production contracts and make any
necessary changes to ensure compliance
with the new regulations. Expected
costs are estimated as the total value of
the time required to review and learn
the rulemaking and then review and, if
necessary, revise procurement and
production contracts.
AMS expects the direct administrative
costs of complying with the Proposed
Alternative’s §§ 201.304 and 201.306
would be relatively small. USDA policy
has long held that several of the
provisions in the Proposed Alternative’s
§§ 201.304 and 201.306 or similar
provisions were violations of the P&S
Act, although the position has not been
established in regulations.
Consequently, AMS expects packers,
live poultry dealers, and swine
contractors to make changes to
relatively few contracts.
Estimates of the amount of time
required to review and learn the
proposed rule and to review and revise
contracts and keep records were
provided by AMS subject matter
experts. These experts were economists
and supervisors with many years of
experience in AMS’s PSD conducting
investigations and compliance reviews
of regulated entities. In May 2020, U.S.
Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) released
Occupational Employment and Wage
Statistics that AMS used for the time
values in this analysis.156 BLS estimated
an average hourly wage for general and
operations managers in animal
slaughtering and processing to be
$65.84. The average hourly wage for
lawyers in food manufacturing was
$80.39. In applying the cost estimates,
AMS marked-up the wages by 41.56
percent to account for fringe benefits.
AMS expects that each packer, swine
contractor, and live poultry dealer
would spend one hour of legal time and
one hour of management time to review
and learn the rulemaking and then
review and, if necessary, revise
156 Estimates are available at U.S. Bureau of Labor
Statistics. Occupational Employment and Wage
Statistics, available at https://www.bls.gov/oes/
special.requests/oesm20all.zip (accessed 8/9/2022).
VerDate Sep<11>2014
20:25 Sep 30, 2022
Jkt 259001
production and marketing contracts to
ensure compliance with the rulemaking.
Live poultry dealers are currently
required to file form PSD 3002, ‘‘Annual
Report of Live Poultry Dealers,’’ OMB
control number 0581–0308, with AMS.
Eighty-nine live poultry dealers filed
annual reports with AMS for their 2020
fiscal year.
Packers are currently required to file
form PSD 3004, ‘‘Annual Report of
Packers’’ OMB control number 0581–
0308, with AMS. Among other things,
each packer reports the number of head
of cattle or calves, hogs, and lamb,
sheep, or goats that it processed. Three
hundred sixty-two packers that
processed cattle or calves, hogs, or lamb,
sheep or goats filed reports with AMS
for their fiscal year 2020. Two hundred
forty-eight were beef or veal packers.
Two hundred eight were pork packers,
and 147 were lamb, sheep, or goat
packers.157 The number of beef, pork,
and lamb packers do not sum to 362
because many firms slaughtered more
than one species of livestock. For
instance, 119 packers slaughtered both
beef and pork, and 75 slaughtered beef,
pork, and lamb.
AMS expects that packers processing
more than one species of livestock will
not incur additional costs for each
species. That is, AMS expects that each
packer will require one hour of
attorney’s time and one hour of
management time regardless of how
many species of livestock it processes.
To allocate costs across (1) beef, (2)
pork, and (3) lamb processors, AMS
allocated one-third of the costs to each
of (1) beef, (2) pork, and (3) lamb for
packers that processed all three species.
For packers processing any two, AMS
allocated one half the costs to each.
AMS estimated that all live poultry
dealers that are regulated under the
Proposed Alternative would require 1
hour of an attorney’s time costing the
industry $10,000 158 and 1 hour of
management time costing the industry
$8,000 159 for learning the rulemaking,
reviewing, and adjusting contracts. The
total costs for learning, reviewing, and
adjusting contracts would be $18,000 160
for live poultry dealers. AMS also
expects that rulemaking will cost all 575
swine contractors an hour of an
attorney’s time and 1 hour of
157 For brevity, all beef and veal packers will be
collectively referred to as beef packers and all lamb,
sheep, and goat packers will be collectively referred
to as lamb packers.
158 89 live poultry dealers × $113.80 per hour ×
1 hour = $10,128.
159 89 live poultry dealers × $93.20 per hour × 1
hour = $8,295.
160 $10,128 + $8,295 = $18,423.
PO 00000
Frm 00037
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
60045
management time costing a total of
$119,000 across all swine contractors.161
AMS expects that packers would
require an estimated 1 hour of an
attorney’s time and 1 hour of
management time costing the industry
$75,000.162 Pork packers’ share of the
packers’ costs would be $27,000.
Combining costs to pork packers with
costs to swine contractors arrives at a
total cost of $146,000 for hogs and pork
markets.
AMS estimates that beef packers and
lamb packers would also require 1 hour
of attorney’s time and 1 hour of
management time to learn the
rulemaking, review, and revise
contracts. The total costs for would be
$33,224 for beef packers and $14,697 for
lamb packers.
Direct Recordkeeping Costs
As presented in detail in the
Paperwork Reduction Act (PRA) section,
costs to comply with the proposed
recordkeeping requirements are likely
relatively low. Proposed § 201.304(c)
requires specific records that, if the
regulated entity maintains, should be
kept for a period of five years, including
policies and procedures, staff training
materials, materials informing covered
producers regarding reporting
mechanisms and protections,
compliance testing, board of directors’
oversight materials, and any records of
the number and nature of unduly
prejudicial or discrimination-based
complaints received.
Costs of recordkeeping, as described
in detail in the PRA, include regulated
entities maintaining and updating
compliance records, and is considered a
direct cost. Some smaller regulated
entities that currently don’t maintain
records, may voluntarily decide to
develop formal policies, procedures,
training, etc. to comply with the
rulemaking and would then have
records to maintain.
As described in detail in the PRA
section, AMS expects the recordkeeping
costs would be comprised of the time
required by regulated entities to store
and maintain records. AMS expects that
the costs will be relatively small
because many packers, live poultry
dealers, and swine contractors may
currently have few records concerning
policies and procedures, staff training
materials, materials informing covered
producers regarding reporting
mechanisms and protections,
compliance testing, and board of
161 575 × ($113.80 per hour × 1 hour + $93.20 per
hour × 1 hour) = $119,027.
162 362 × ($113.80 per hour × 1 hour + $93.20 per
hour × 1 hour) = $74,935.
E:\FR\FM\03OCP3.SGM
03OCP3
60046
Federal Register / Vol. 87, No. 190 / Monday, October 3, 2022 / Proposed Rules
directors’ oversight materials related to
prejudicial treatment. Some smaller
firms might not have any records to
store. Others already store the records
and may have no new costs.
As described in detail in the PRA,
AMS estimated that recordkeeping time
for larger entities will be greater than for
smaller entities, and thus estimated
costs by quartiles, from largest entities
to smallest. AMS estimated that
proposed § 201.304(c) would require
packers, live poultry dealers, and swine
contractors in each quartile an average
4.00 hours, 2.00 hours, 1.33 hours, and
0.67 hours of administrative time for the
first, second, third, and fourth quartiles,
respectively. Additionally, AMS
estimated that the hours required of
managers, attorneys, and information
technology staff each will average 1.50
hours, 0.75 hours, 0.50 hours, and 0.25
hours for the first, second, third, and
fourth quartiles, respectively.
As delineated in detail in the PRA,
AMS also expects that packers, live
poultry dealers, and swine contractors
will incur continuing recordkeeping
costs in each successive year. AMS
estimated that proposed § 201.304(c)
would require an average of 3.00 hours,
1.50 hours, 1.00 hour, and 0.50 hour of
administrative assistant time; 1.50
hours, 0.75 hour, 0.50 hour, and 0.25
hour of time each from managers and
attorneys; and 1.00 hour, 0.50 hour, 0.33
hour, and 0.17 hour of time from
information technology staff for packers,
live poultry dealers, and swine
contractors in the first, second, third,
and fourth quartiles, respectively, to
setup and maintain the required records
in each succeeding year.
As described in detail in the PRA,
estimated first-year costs for
recordkeeping requirements in proposed
§ 201.304(c) total $26,000 for live
poultry dealers,163 $170,000 for swine
contractors,164 and $107,000 for
packers. Estimated yearly continuing
costs for recordkeeping requirements in
§ 201.304(c) total $23,000 for live
poultry dealers,165 $147,000 for swine
contractors,166 and $93,000 for
packers.167
Breaking out costs by market, AMS
expects recordkeeping requirements in
proposed § 201.304(c) to cost beef
packers $47,000 in the first year and
$41,000 in each following year, as
described in detail in the PRA. Proposed
§ 201.304(c) would cost lamb packers
$21,000 in the first year and $18,000 in
successive years. Proposed § 201.304(c)
would cost pork packers $39,000, and it
would cost swine contractors $170,000
for a total of $209,000 in the first year.
Proposed § 201.304(c) would cost swine
contractors $147,000 in successive
years, and it would cost pork packers
$33,000 for a total $180,000.
Total Direct Administrative and
Recordkeeping Costs
The below table summarizes
combined expected administrative and
recordkeeping costs for regulated
entities in the first year and in
succeeding years. AMS expects that
administrative and recordkeeping costs
associated with Proposed Alternative
§§ 201.304 and 201.306 would cost each
packer, swine contractor, and live
poultry dealer an average $504 in the
first year and an average $256 in each
succeeding year. First-year costs would
total $45,000 for live poultry dealers,
$290,000 for swine contractors, and
$182,000 for packers. Costs in
successive years would be due to
recordkeeping requirements and would
total $23,000 for live poultry dealers,
$147,000 for swine contractors, and
$93,000 for packers annually.
TABLE 7—EXPECTED FIRST-YEAR COST AND SUCCEEDING YEARS COSTS FOR LIVE POULTRY DEALERS, PACKERS, AND
SWINE CONTRACTORS
First-year cost
($)
Cost for each
succeeding
year
($)
Average Cost per Live Poultry Dealer .....................................................................................................................
Average Cost per to Swine Contractor ...................................................................................................................
Average Cost per Packer ........................................................................................................................................
Total Cost to Live Poultry Dealers ..........................................................................................................................
Total Cost to Swine Contractors .............................................................................................................................
Total Cost to Packers ..............................................................................................................................................
Beef Packers * ..................................................................................................................................................
Pork Packers * ..................................................................................................................................................
Lamb Packers * .................................................................................................................................................
504
504
504
45,000
290,000
182,000
80,000
66,000
36,000
256
256
256
23,000
147,000
** 93,000
41,000
33,000
18,000
Total Cost ..................................................................................................................................................
517,000
263,000
lotter on DSK11XQN23PROD with PROPOSALS3
* Many packers process more than one species of livestock, but AMS expects that each packer will require one hour of attorney’s time and
one hour of management time regardless of how many species of livestock it processes. To allocate costs across (1) beef, (2) pork, and (3) lamb
processors, AMS allocated one-third of the costs to each of (1) beef, (2) pork, and (3) lamb for packers that processed all three species.
** Column total may not sum due to rounding.
163 89 live poultry dealers × (($39.69 per hour
admin. cost × (4 hours + 2 hours + 1.33 hours +
.67 hours)) + ($93.20 per hour manager cost × (1.5
hours + .75 hours + .5 hours + .25 hours)) +
($113.80 legal cost × (1.5 hours + .75 hours + .5
hours + .25 hours)) + ($82.50 information tech cost
× (1.5 hours + .75 hours + .5 hours + .25 hours))/
4 = $26,390.
164 (575 swine contractors × (($39.69 per hour
admin. cost × (4 hours + 2 hours + 1.33 hours +
.67 hours)) + ($93.20 per hour manager cost × (1.5
hours + .75 hours + .5 hours + .25 hours)) + (113.80
legal cost × (1.5 hours + .75 hours + .5 hours + .25
VerDate Sep<11>2014
20:25 Sep 30, 2022
Jkt 259001
hours)) + ($82.50 information tech cost × (1.5 hours
+ .75 hours + .5 hours + .25 hours)))/4 = $170,496.
165 (89 live poultry dealers × (($39.69 per hour
admin. cost × (4 hours + 2 hours + 1.33 hours +
.67 hours)) + ($93.20 per hour manager cost × (1.5
hours + .75 hours + .5 hours + .25 hours)) +
($113.80 legal cost × (1.5 hours + .75 hours + .5
hours + .25 hours)) + $82.50 information tech cost
× (1.5 hours + .75 hours + .5 hours + .25 hours)))/
4 = $22,788.
166 (575 swine contractors × (($39.69 per hour
admin. cost × (4 hours + 2 hours + 1.33 hours +
.67 hours)) + ($93.20 per hour manager cost × (1.5
PO 00000
Frm 00038
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
hours + .75 hours + .5 hours + .25 hours)) +
($113.80 legal cost × (1.5 hours + .75 hours + .5
hours + .25 hours)) + ($82.50 information tech cost
× (1.5 hours + .75 hours + .5 hours + .25 hours)))/
4 = $147,225.
167 (362 packers × ($39.69 per hour admin. cost
× (4 hours + 2 hours + 1.33 hours + .67 hours)) +
($93.20 per hour manager cost × (1.5 hours + .75
hours + .5 hours + .25 hours)) + ($113.80 legal cost
× (1.5 hours + .75 hours + .5 hours + .25 hours))
+ ($82.50 information tech cost × (1.5 hours + .75
hours + .5 hours + .25 hours)))/4 = $92,688.
E:\FR\FM\03OCP3.SGM
03OCP3
60047
Federal Register / Vol. 87, No. 190 / Monday, October 3, 2022 / Proposed Rules
The total direct administrative and
recordkeeping costs are estimated to be
$517,000 in the first year. Estimated first
year total direct administrative and
recordkeeping costs for the cattle and
beef industry, hogs and pork, lamb, and
poultry industries rounded to the
nearest thousand dollars are listed in
the following table.
TABLE 8—DIRECT ADMINISTRATIVE AND RECORDKEEPING COSTS FOR PROPOSED §§ 201.304 AND 201.306 IN 2022
Cattle
($ Th)
80
Regulatory Alternative 2—Proposed
Alternative: Ten-Year Total Direct
Administrative and Recordkeeping
Costs
Hogs
($ Th)
Lambs
($ Th)
Poultry
($ Th)
Total
($ Th)
355
36
45
517
§§ 201.304 and 201.306 for each year
from 2022 through 2031 appear in the
table below.
Expected administrative and
recordkeeping costs of proposed
TABLE 9—TEN-YEAR TOTAL DIRECT ADMINISTRATIVE AND RECORDKEEPING COSTS OF PROPOSED §§ 201.304 AND
201.306 *
Cattle
($ Th)
Year
2022
2023
2024
2025
2026
2027
2028
2029
2030
2031
Hogs
($ Th)
Lambs
($ Th)
Poultry
($ Th)
Total
($ Th)
.....................................................................................
.....................................................................................
.....................................................................................
.....................................................................................
.....................................................................................
.....................................................................................
.....................................................................................
.....................................................................................
.....................................................................................
.....................................................................................
80
41
41
41
41
41
41
41
41
41
355
181
181
181
181
181
181
181
181
181
36
18
18
18
18
18
18
18
18
18
45
23
23
23
23
23
23
23
23
23
517
263
263
263
263
263
263
263
263
263
Totals ............................................................................
449
1,982
200
250
2,881
** Column total may not sum due to rounding.
Based on the analysis, AMS expects
the ten-year total direct administrative
and recordkeeping costs of proposed
§§ 201.304 and 201.306 to be $2.9
million.
Regulatory Alternative 2—Proposed
Alternative: Present Value of Ten-Year
Total Direct Administrative and
Recordkeeping Costs
lotter on DSK11XQN23PROD with PROPOSALS3
Costs to be incurred in the future are
lower than the same costs to be incurred
today. This is because the money that
will be used to pay the costs in the
future can be invested today and earn a
return on investment until the period in
which the cost is incurred. After the
VerDate Sep<11>2014
20:25 Sep 30, 2022
Jkt 259001
cost has been incurred, the earned
returns will still be available.
To account for the time value of
money, the administrative costs to be
incurred in the future are discounted
back to today’s dollars using a discount
rate. The sum of all costs discounted
back to the present is called the present
value (PV) of total costs. AMS relied on
both a three percent and seven percent
discount rate as discussed in Circular
A–4.168
AMS calculated the PV of the ten-year
total direct administrative and
recordkeeping costs of the proposed
regulations using a three percent and
seven percent discount rate and the PVs
appear in the following table.
168 Circular A–4. December 17, 2003, available at
www.whitehouse.gov/sites/whitehouse.gov/files/
omb/circulars/A4/a-4.pdf (accessed 01/10/2022).
PO 00000
Frm 00039
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
E:\FR\FM\03OCP3.SGM
03OCP3
60048
Federal Register / Vol. 87, No. 190 / Monday, October 3, 2022 / Proposed Rules
AMS expects the annualized ten-year
TABLE 10—PV OF TEN-YEAR DIRECT
ADMINISTRATIVE
AND
RECORD- administrative and recordkeeping costs
KEEPING COST OF §§ 201.304 AND of proposed §§ 201.304 and 201.306 to
be $292,000 at a three percent discount
201.306
Discount rate
3 Percent ..............................
7 Percent ..............................
Proposed
alternative
($ th)
2,487
2,082
AMS expects the PV of the ten-year
total administrative and recordkeeping
costs of proposed §§ 201.304 and
201.306 to be $2.5 million at a three
percent discount rate and $2.1 million
at a seven percent discount rate.
Regulatory Alternative 2—Proposed
Alternative: Annualized PV of Ten-Year
Total Direct Administrative and
Recordkeeping Costs
AMS then annualized the PV of the
ten-year total administrative and
recordkeeping costs (referred to as
annualized costs) of proposed
§§ 201.304 and 201.306 using both a
three percent and seven percent
discount rate as required by Circular A–
4 and the results appear in the following
table.169
rate and $297,000 at a seven percent
discount rate.
Cost-Benefit Comparison of Proposed
Alternative
Combined sales of beef, pork, and
broiler chicken in the U.S. for 2019 were
approximately $240 billion. As
discussed above, the total cost of
proposed §§ 201.304 and 201.306 in the
first year is estimated to be $517,000, or
0.000002 percent of revenues. A
reduction in prejudicial, discriminatory,
retaliatory, and deceptive practices
would lead to benefits that would be
directly related to the reductions in
these practices. If the reductions are
small, the benefits would be small. The
greater the reductions, the greater the
benefits. AMS expects that the net
benefits to society from the proposed
rule will be very small in relation to the
total value of industry production,
leading to negligible indirect effects on
industry supply and demand, including
price and quantity effects.
Regulatory Alternative 3: Small
Business Exemption Alternative
TABLE 11—ANNUALIZED DIRECT ADThe third regulatory alternative that
MINISTRATIVE AND RECORDKEEPING
COSTS OF PROPOSED §§ 201.304 AMS considered is issuing proposed
§§ 201.304 and 201.306, but exempting
AND 201.306
Discount rate
small businesses, as defined by the SBA,
from compliance with the
recordkeeping requirement of
§ 201.304(c).170 All other provisions of
§§ 201.304 and 201.306 would still
292
297 apply to small businesses. Most packers
are small businesses under the SBA
Proposed
alternative
($ th)
3 Percent ..............................
7 Percent ..............................
definition. Of the 362 packers reporting
to AMS, 346 are small businesses. Two
hundred forty-two beef packers and 197
pork packers are small businesses. All
147 lamb packers are small businesses.
Packers include multi-species packers.
One hundred eight swine contractors
are small businesses. There are 54 small
poultry dealers.
Regulatory Alternative 3: Total Costs of
the Small Business Exemption
Alternative
The below table summarizes
combined expected administrative and
recordkeeping costs for regulated
entities in the first year and in
succeeding years. AMS expects that
administrative and recordkeeping costs
associated with Proposed Alternative
§§ 201.304 and 201.306 would cost each
live poultry dealer, swine contractor,
and packer an average of $398, $485,
$231, respectively, in the first year.
AMS expects costs to average $165,
$256, and $23 for live poultry dealers,
swine contractors, and packers,
respectively, in each succeeding year.
First-year costs would total $35,000 for
live poultry dealers, $279,000 for swine
contractors, and $84,000 for packers.
Costs in successive years would be due
to recordkeeping requirements and
would total $15,000 for live poultry
dealers, $138,000 for swine contractors,
and $8,000 for packers annually. The
total direct administrative and
recordkeeping costs are estimated to be
$398,000 in the first year.
TABLE 12—SMALL BUSINESS RECORD KEEPING EXEMPTION ALTERNATIVE EXPECTED FIRST-YEAR COST AND SUCCEEDING
YEARS COSTS FOR LIVE POULTRY DEALERS, PACKERS, AND SWINE CONTRACTORS
lotter on DSK11XQN23PROD with PROPOSALS3
First year cost
($)
Cost for each
succeeding
year
($)
Average Cost per Live Poultry Dealer .....................................................................................................................
Average Cost per Swine Contractor ........................................................................................................................
Average Cost per Packer ........................................................................................................................................
Total Cost to Live Poultry Dealers ..........................................................................................................................
Total Cost to Swine Contractors .............................................................................................................................
Total Cost to Packers ..............................................................................................................................................
Beef Packers * ..................................................................................................................................................
Pork Packers * ..................................................................................................................................................
Lamb Packers * .................................................................................................................................................
398
485
231
35,000
279,000
84,000
36,000
33,000
15,000
165
256
23
15,000
138,000
8,000
3,000
5,000
0
Total Cost ..................................................................................................................................................
398,000
161,000
* Many packers process more than one species of livestock, but AMS expects that each packer will require one hour of attorney’s time and
one hour of management time regardless of how many species of livestock it processes. To allocate costs across (1) beef, (2) pork, and (3) lamb
processors, AMS allocated one-third of the costs to each of (1) beef, (2) pork, and (3) lamb for packers that processed all three species.
169 Ibid.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
170 See, ‘‘Stay legally compliant (sba.gov),’’
available at https://www.sba.gov/business-guide/
20:25 Sep 30, 2022
Jkt 259001
PO 00000
Frm 00040
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
manage-your-business/stay-legally-compliant (Last
accessed 8/9/2022).
E:\FR\FM\03OCP3.SGM
03OCP3
Federal Register / Vol. 87, No. 190 / Monday, October 3, 2022 / Proposed Rules
lotter on DSK11XQN23PROD with PROPOSALS3
As discussed above, AMS considers
the total costs from proposed §§ 201.304
and 201.306 to be increased direct
administrative and recordkeeping costs
with no indirect costs from adjustments
by the cattle, hog, and poultry industries
to reduce their use of AMAs, change
pricing mechanisms or poultry
tournaments, and no substantial
changes to existing marketing, growing,
or production contracts. AMS estimated
the costs to small business from the
direct administrative costs of §§ 201.304
and 201.306 but excluded the
recordkeeping costs of § 201.304(c) in
this alternative option.
AMS estimated the costs to small
business to be the value of the time for
management, attorneys, administrative
staff, and information technology staff to
review the rulemaking and the firms’
practices determining compliance with
the direct administrative costs of
§§ 201.304 and 201.306. AMS estimated
costs for the Small Business Exemption
Alternative similarly to the Proposed
Alternative. The only difference is the
recordkeeping costs of § 201.304(c)
attributable to small business are not
included in the costs for the Small
Business Exemption Alternative. The
estimates appear in the table below. The
Proposed Alternative is also shown for
convenience.
approximately $140,000 in the first year
and $1.1 million over ten years.
Regulatory Alternative 3: PV of Total
Costs of the Small Business Exemption
Alternative
AMS calculated the PV of the ten-year
total costs of the Small Business
Exemption Alternative using both a
three percent and seven percent
discount rate and the PVs appear in the
following table. The Proposed
Alternative is also shown for
convenience.
TABLE 14—PV OF TEN-YEAR TOTAL
COST—SMALL BUSINESS EXEMPTION
60049
the Small Business Exemption
Alternative by subtracting the
annualized costs of the Small Business
Exemption Alternative from those of the
Proposed Alternative and the results
appear in the following table.
TABLE 16—DIFFERENCE IN TEN-YEAR
ANNUALIZED COSTS OF PROPOSED
§§ 201.304 AND 201.306 BETWEEN
PROPOSED ALTERNATIVE AND SMALL
BUSINESS EXEMPTION ALTERNATIVE
Discount rate
3 Percent ..............................
7 Percent ..............................
Small
business
exemption
alternative
($ th)
($ th)
108
107
The annualized costs of the Small
Business Exemption Alternative are
$108,000 less expensive using a three
percent discount rate and $107,000 less
expensive using a seven percent
3 Percent ..
2,487
1,567 discount rate. As is the case with costs,
7 Percent ..
2,082
1,331 the benefits will be highest for the
Proposed Alternative because the full
AMS expects the PV of the ten-year
benefits will be received by all livestock
total costs of proposed §§ 201.304 and
producers and growers, not just those
201.306 with a small business
doing business with large packers,
exemption to be $1.6 million at a three
swine contractors and live poultry
percent discount rate and $1.3 million
dealers.
at a seven percent discount rate.
Though the Small Business
Exemption Alternative would save
Regulatory Alternative 3: Annualized
between $108,000 and $106,000 on an
Costs of the Small Business Exemption
annualized basis, this alternative would
Alternative
deny the potential benefits offered by
TABLE 13—ANNUAL TOTAL DIRECT
AMS then annualized the PV of the
proposed § 201.304(c) to all livestock
COSTS—SMALL BUSINESS EXEMP- ten-year total costs of proposed
producers, swine contract growers, and
TION ALTERNATIVE
§§ 201.304 and 201.306 with a small
poultry growers who contract with
business exemption using both a three
Small
percent and seven percent discount rate small packers, swine contractors, and
Proposed
business
live poultry dealers. While most cattle,
and the results appear in the following
Year
alternative
exemption
hogs, and poultry processed and grown
table. The Proposed Alternative is also
($ th)
alternative
are contracted with large businesses,
($ th)
shown for convenience.
there are many small businesses who
would be exempt from keeping records
2022 ..................
517
376
TABLE 15—TEN-YEAR ANNUALIZED
under proposed § 201.304(c) if the Small
2023 ..................
263
161
2024 ..................
263
161 COSTS—SMALL BUSINESS EXEMPTION Business Exemption Alternative is
2025 ..................
263
161
chosen. The Small Business Exemption
Small
2026 ..................
263
161
Alternative of the recordkeeping
Proposed
business
Discount
2027 ..................
263
161
requirement of § 201.304(c) would
alternative
exemption
rate
2028 ..................
263
161
($ th)
alternative
exempt all lamb processors and deny
2029 ..................
263
161
($ th)
the potential benefits to all lamb
2030 ..................
263
161
2031 ..................
263
161 3 Percent ..
292
184 producers. Under this alternative, these
7 Percent ..
297
190 livestock producers, poultry growers
Totals .........
2,881
1,809
and swine production contract growers
would be denied the potential benefits
AMS expects the annualized costs of
AMS estimates that proposed
proposed §§ 201.304 and 201.306 with a of recordkeeping and improved
corporate culture as discussed above in
§§ 201.304 and 201.306, with the small
small business exemption to be
business exemption, will result in $376
$184,000 at a three percent discount rate the section on Regulatory Alternative 2:
Benefits of the Proposed Alternative.
thousand in direct total costs in the
and $190,000 at a seven percent
cattle, hog, lamb, and poultry industries discount rate.
AMS considered all three regulatory
in the first full year following
alternatives and believes that the
Cost-Benefit Comparison of Regulatory
implementation and $161 thousand
Proposed Alternative is the best
each year in ongoing costs. AMS expects Alternatives
alternative as it benefits all livestock
The status quo alternative has zero
the ten-year total costs of proposed
producers, swine production contract
marginal costs. AMS compared the
§§ 201.304 and 201.306 with a small
growers, and poultry growers, regardless
annualized costs of the Proposed
business exemption to be $1.8 million.
of the size of the packer, swine
Alternative to the annualized costs of
Exempting small business would save
contractor, or live poultry dealer with
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:11 Sep 30, 2022
Jkt 259001
Discount
rate
PO 00000
Frm 00041
Proposed
alternative
($ th)
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
E:\FR\FM\03OCP3.SGM
03OCP3
60050
Federal Register / Vol. 87, No. 190 / Monday, October 3, 2022 / Proposed Rules
which they contract above the Status
Quo Alternative.
lotter on DSK11XQN23PROD with PROPOSALS3
Regulatory Flexibility Analysis
Proposed § 201.304 prohibits
retaliation by regulated entities by
terminating contracts, non-renewal of
contracts, refusing to deal, and
interfering in farm real estate contracts
as unduly prejudicial and
discriminatory practices. Proposed
§ 201.306 prohibits deceptive practices
by regulated entities in contracting with
covered producers including making or
modifying a contract, performing under
or enforcing a contract, terminating a
contract, or refusing to contract with a
covered producer based on pretext, false
or misleading statements, or omission of
material facts.
Additionally, the Proposed
Alternative’s § 201.304(c) requires
packers, live poultry dealers, and swine
contractors to keep relevant records of
policies and procedures, staff training
materials, materials informing covered
producers regarding reporting
mechanisms and protections,
compliance testing, and board of
directors’ oversight materials related to
prejudicial treatment.
The SBA defines small businesses by
their North American Industry
Classification System Codes (NAICS).171
Live poultry dealers, NAICS 311615, are
considered small businesses if they have
fewer than 1,250 employees. Meat
packers, including, beef, veal, pork,
lamb, and goat packers, NAICS 311611,
are small businesses if they have fewer
than 1,000 employees. Swine
contractors, NAICS 112210, are
considered small if their sales are less
than $1 million annually.
AMS maintains data on live poultry
dealers from the annual reports these
firms file with AMS. Currently, 89 live
poultry dealers would be subject to the
proposed regulation. Fifty-four of the
live poultry dealers would be small
businesses according to the SBA
standard.
AMS records identified 362 packers
that file annual reports with PSD for
their 2020 fiscal year. Two hundred
forty-eight were beef packers. Two
hundred eight were pork packers, and
147 were lamb or goat packers. Many
firms slaughtered more than one species
of livestock. For instance, 118 packers
slaughtered both beef and pork.
171 U.S. Small Business Administration. Table of
Small Business Size Standards Matched to North
American Industry Classification System Codes.
effective August 19, 2019. ‘‘The SBA Issues a Final
Rule to Adopt NAICS 2017 for Small Business Size’’
(last accessed 8/9/2022). Available at https://
www.sba.gov/article/2018/feb/27/sba-issues-finalrule-adopt-naics-2017-small-business-sizestandards.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
20:25 Sep 30, 2022
Jkt 259001
Most packers would be small
businesses, although large packers are
responsible for most meat production.
Three hundred forty-six packers would
be small businesses. Two hundred fortytwo beef packers and 197 pork packers
were small businesses. All of the 147
lamb and goat packers were small
businesses.
AMS does not have similar records for
swine contractors because they are not
required to register with AMS or
provide annual reports. Table 24 of the
2017 USDA Census of Agriculture
indicated that there were 575 swine
contractors in 2017. The Census of
Agriculture table has categories for the
number of head that swine contractors
sold, but not the value of the head sold.
AMS expects that the 467 swine
contractors that sold 5,000 head of hogs
or more were large businesses, and the
108 contractors that sold less than 5,000
head were small businesses.
AMS estimated the costs in two parts.
First, AMS expects that each packer,
swine contractor, and live poultry
dealer would review and learn the new
rulemaking and then review and, if
necessary, revise production and
marketing contracts to ensure
compliance with the new rulemaking.
Second, AMS expects that packers, live
poultry dealers, and swine contractors
would have additional costs associated
with the new recordkeeping
requirements in proposed § 201.304(c).
AMS estimated that costs reviewing
and learning the Proposed Alternative to
small live poultry dealers, small
packers, and small swine contractors
would consist of one hour of a
manager’s time and one hour of a
lawyer’s time to review the
requirements of proposed §§ 201.304
and 201.306. Expected first-year costs
would be $207 172 for each live poultry
dealer, each swine contractor, and each
packer. This would amount to a total
$11,000 for the 54 live poultry dealers,
$72,000 for the 346 packers, and
$22,000 for the 108 swine contractors.
Concerning the recordkeeping
requirements in the Proposed
Alternative’s § 201.304(c), AMS expects
the cost would be comprised of the time
required to store and maintain records.
AMS expects that the costs will be
relatively small because packers, live
poultry dealers, and swine contractors
would likely have few records
concerning policies and procedures,
staff training materials, materials
informing covered producers regarding
reporting mechanisms and protections,
172 $113.80 per hour × 1 hour of an attorney’s
time + $93.20 per hour × 1 hour of a manager’s time
= $207.
PO 00000
Frm 00042
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
compliance testing, and board of
directors’ oversight materials related to
prejudicial treatment. Many firms might
not have any records to maintain.
Others already maintain the records and
have no new costs.
AMS expects that recordkeeping costs
would be correlated with the size of the
firms. AMS ranked packers, live poultry
dealers, and swine contractors by size
and grouped them into quartiles,
estimating more recordkeeping time for
larger entities than for the smaller
entities. AMS estimated that proposed
§ 201.304(c) would require an average of
4.00 hours of administrative assistant
time, 1.50 hours of time each from
managers, attorneys, and information
technology staff for packers, live poultry
dealers, and swine contractors in the
first quartile, containing the largest
entities, to setup and maintain the
required records in the first year. AMS
expects the packers, live poultry
dealers, and swine contractors in the
second quartile would require an
average of 2.00 hours of administrative
assistant time, 0.75 hours of time each
from managers, attorneys, and
information technology staff for first
year costs. The third quartile would
require 1.33 hours of administrative
assistant time, 0.50 hours of time each
from managers, attorneys, and
information technology staff for first
year costs, and the fourth quartile,
containing the smallest entities, would
require 0.67 hours of administrative
assistant time, 0.25 hours of time each
from managers, attorneys, and
information technology staff.
AMS also expects that packers, live
poultry dealers, and swine contractors
will incur continuing costs in each
successive year. AMS estimated that
proposed § 201.304(c) would require an
average of 3.00 hours of administrative
assistant time, 1.50 hours of time each
from managers and attorneys, and 1.00
hour of time from information
technology staff for packers, live poultry
dealers, and swine contractors in the
first quartile to setup and maintain the
required records in each succeeding
year. AMS expects the packers, live
poultry dealers, and swine contractors
in the second quartile would require an
average of 1.50 hours of administrative
assistant time, 0.75 hours of time each
from managers and attorneys, and 0.50
hours of time from information
technology staff in each succeeding
year. The third quartile would require
1.00 hour of administrative assistant
time, 0.50 hours of time each from
managers and attorneys, and 0.33 hours
of time from information technology
staff in each succeeding year, and the
fourth quartile would require 0.50 hours
E:\FR\FM\03OCP3.SGM
03OCP3
60051
Federal Register / Vol. 87, No. 190 / Monday, October 3, 2022 / Proposed Rules
of administrative assistant time, 0.25
hours of time each from managers and
attorneys, and 0.17 hours from
information technology staff.
Estimated first-year costs for
recordkeeping requirements in the
Proposed Alternative’s § 201.304(c)
totaled $9,000 for live poultry
dealers,173 $11,000 for swine
contractors,174 and $98,000 for
packers.175 Estimated yearly continuing
costs for recordkeeping requirements in
§ 201.304(c) totaled $8,000 for live
poultry dealers,176 $9,000 for swine
contractors,177 and $84,000 for
packers.178
Total expected first year costs,
including one time reviewing costs and
recordkeeping cost would be $169,000
for packers, $33,000 for swine
contractors, and $21,000 for live poultry
dealers. Table 17 lists expected costs for
small businesses subject to proposed
§§ 201.304 and 201.306. AMS expects
marginal costs to total $223,000 in the
first year. Ten-year costs annualized at
3 percent would be $94,000 for packers,
$12,000 for swine contractors, and
$10,000 for live poultry dealers. Total
ten-year costs annualized at 3 percent
would be expected to be $116,000.
Ten-year costs annualized at 7 percent
would be $96,000 for packers, $12,000
for swine contractors, and $10,000 for
live poultry dealers. Total ten-year costs
annualized at 7 percent would be
expected to be $118,000.
TABLE 17—ESTIMATED INDUSTRY TOTAL COSTS TO SMALL BUSINESSES
Packers
($)
Estimate type
First-Year Costs ...............................................................................................
10 years Annualized at 3 Percent ...................................................................
10 years Annualized at 7 Percent ...................................................................
Live poultry dealers annually file
reports with AMS that list each firm’s
net sales. Packers that purchase more
than $500,000 annually in livestock also
file annual reports that list net sales.
While packers that annually slaughter
less than $500,000 in livestock also file
annual reports with AMS, in order to
reduce the reporting requirements for
small packers, they are not required to
provide annual net sales.
Data from the annual reports enables
AMS to compare average net sales for
small pork packers, beef packers, and
live poultry dealers to the expected
costs of proposed §§ 201.304 and
201.306 in the table below. A
shortcoming in the comparison is that
169,000
94,000
96,000
net sales for smallest packers, those that
purchase less than $500,000 in
livestock, are not included in the
average.
Swine contractors are not required to
file annual reports with AMS, and
similar net sales data are not available
for swine contractors. Census of
Agriculture’s data have the number of
head sold by size classes for farms that
sold their own hogs and pigs in 2017
and that identified themselves as
contractors or integrators, but not the
value of sales nor the number of head
sold from the farms of the contracted
production. To estimate average revenue
per establishment, AMS used the
estimated average value per head for
Swine
contractors
($)
33,000
12,000
12,000
Poultry
processors
($)
21,000
10,000
10,000
Total
($)
223,000
116,000
118,000
sales of all swine operations and the
production values for firms in the
Agriculture Census size classes for
swine contractors.
The following table compares the
average per entity first-year costs of the
Proposed Alternative’s §§ 201.304 and
201.306 to the average revenue per
establishment for all regulated small
businesses. First-year costs are
appropriate for a threshold analysis
because all the costs would occur in the
first year. First-year costs per regulated
entity are considerably higher than
annualized costs, and any ratio of
annualized costs to revenues will be less
than a ratio of first-year costs to
revenues.
TABLE 18—COMPARISON OF AVERAGE COSTS PER ENTITY TO AVERAGE REVENUES PER ENTITY FOR SMALL BUSINESSES
NAICS
lotter on DSK11XQN23PROD with PROPOSALS3
112210—Swine Contractor ................
311615—Poultry Processor ...............
108
54
173 9.5 live poultry dealers × ($39.69 per hour
admin. cost × 2 hours + $93.20 per hour manger
cost × .75 + $113.80 legal cost × .75 hours + $82.50
information tech cost × .75 hours) + 44.5 live
poultry dealers × ($39.69 per hour admin. cost ×
(1.33 hours + .67 hours) + $93.20 per hour manger
cost × (.5 hours + .25 hours) + $113.80 legal cost
× (.5 hours + .25 hours) + $82.50 information tech
cost × (.5 hours + .25 hours))/2 = $9,414.
174 108 swine contractors × ($39.69 per hour
admin. cost × .67 hours + $93.20 per hour manger
cost × .25 hours + $113.80 legal cost × .25 hours
+ $82.50 information tech cost × .25 hours) =
$10,675.
175 74.5 packers × ($39.69 per hour admin. cost
× 2 hours + $93.20 per hour manger cost × .75 hours
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:13 Sep 30, 2022
Average revenue
or net sales per
establishment
($)
Number of
small
businesses
Jkt 259001
First-year
costs
($)
485,860
50,729,044
306
381
+ $113.80 legal cost × .75 hours + $82.50
information tech cost × .75 hours + 271.5 packers
× ($39.69 per hour admin. cost × (2 hours + 1.33
hours + .67 hours) + $93.20 per hour manger cost
× (.75 hours + .5 hours + .25 hours) + $113.80 legal
cost × (.75 hours + .5 hours + .25 hours) + $82.50
information tech cost × (.75 hours + .5 hours + .25
hours))/3 = $97,850.
176 9.5 live poultry dealers × ($39.69 per hour
admin. cost × 1.5 hours + $93.20 per hour manger
cost × .75 + $113.80 legal cost × .75 hours + $82.50
information tech cost × .75 hours) + 44.5 live
poultry dealers × ($39.69 per hour admin. cost × (1
hours + .5 hours)) + $93.20 per hour manger cost
× (.5 hours + .25 hours)) + ($113.80 legal cost × (.5
hours + .25 hours) + ($82.50 information tech cost
× (.33hours + .17 hours))/2 = $8,129.
PO 00000
Frm 00043
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
First-year cost
as percent of
revenue
(percent)
0.0629
0.0008
Annualized
cost
discounted at
7%
115
181
Annualized
cost as
percent of
revenue
(percent)
0.0236
0.0004
177 108 swine contractors × ($39.69 per hour
admin. cost × .5 hours + $93.20 per hour manger
cost × .25 hours + $113.80 legal cost × .25 hours
+ $82.50 information tech cost × .17 hours) =
$9,217.
178 74.5 packers × ($39.69 per hour admin. cost
× 3 hours + $93.20 per hour manger cost × 1.5 hours
+ $113.80 legal cost × 1.5 hours + $82.50
information tech cost × 1 hour) + 271.5 packers ×
($39.69 per hour admin. cost × (1.5 hours + 1 hours
+ .5 hours) + $93.20 per hour manger cost × (.75
hours + .5 hours + .25 hours) + $113.80 legal cost
× (.75 hours + .5 hours + .25 hours) + $82.50
information tech cost × (.50 hours + .33 hours + .17
hours))/3 = $84,494.
E:\FR\FM\03OCP3.SGM
03OCP3
60052
Federal Register / Vol. 87, No. 190 / Monday, October 3, 2022 / Proposed Rules
TABLE 18—COMPARISON OF AVERAGE COSTS PER ENTITY TO AVERAGE REVENUES PER ENTITY FOR SMALL
BUSINESSES—Continued
Average revenue
or net sales per
establishment
($)
Number of
small
businesses
NAICS
311611—Meat Packer * .....................
346
First-year
costs
($)
83,356,860
First-year cost
as percent of
revenue
(percent)
490
0.0006
Annualized
cost
discounted at
7%
Annualized
cost as
percent of
revenue
(percent)
277
0.0003
* Averages exclude net sales for packers that purchased less than $500,000 in livestock annually.
First-year costs as a percent of
revenues are small. It is highest for
swine contractors because average
revenues for swine contractors are
considerably smaller than average
revenues for packers and live poultry
dealers. At 0.0629 percent, the first-year
cost is small compared to revenue.
Average net sales for packers listed in
Table 18 have the problem of excluding
the smallest packers, and consequently
the averages are biased toward being too
large. However, first-year cost as a
percent of net sales is 0.0006 percent.
Estimated first year cost for each packer
is $490. These are relatively small
numbers. If average net sales for each
packer were only one hundredth of the
amount listed in Table 18, estimated
first-year costs would be less than 0.1
percent of net sales.
AMS has limited data on revenues for
the smallest packers and live poultry
dealers. Eighty-five packers submitted
shortened annual reports to AMS
because they purchased less than
$500,000 in livestock. For the largest of
these packers, annual revenues are
likely close to $500,000 and expected
costs would be about 0.06 percent. AMS
encourages comments concerning
business sizes for packers that purchase
less than $500,000 in livestock each
year and the effect the proposed
§§ 201.304 and 201.306 would have on
their business.
Small Business Exception Alternative
AMS also considered a Small
Business Exception Alternative to the
Proposed Alternative’s §§ 201.304 and
201.306. The Small Business Exception
Alternative would be the same as the
Proposed Alternative’s §§ 201.304 and
201.306 in all respects with the
exception that none of the
recordkeeping requirements in proposed
§ 201.304(c) would apply to small
businesses. This Small Business
Exception Alternative would cost small
packers, swine contractors, and live
poultry dealers less than proposed
§§ 201.304 and 201.306 would cost.
Recordkeeping costs comprised the
largest share of the costs associated with
§§ 201.304 and 201.306.
Although the Small Business
Exception Alternative would not require
small businesses to keep any additional
records, small businesses would still be
required to comply with all of the other
provisions of §§ 201.304 and 201.306.
AMS expects that small live poultry
dealers, small packers, and small swine
contractors would need to review the
new rulemaking and determine whether
the proposed rule would require any
changes to their procurement contracts
or other business practices and make the
necessary changes. AMS estimated that
costs would consist of one hour of a
manager’s time and one hour of a
lawyer’s time to review the
requirements of Proposed Alternative’s
§§ 201.304 and 201.306. This amounts
to expected first-year costs of $207 179
for each live poultry dealer, each swine
contractor, and each packer that
qualifies as small business. All costs
would occur in the first year.
Table 19 lists expected costs for small
businesses subject to the Small Business
Exception Alternative. AMS expects
marginal costs to total $105,000 in the
first year. The Small Business Exception
Alternative is expected to cost $72,000,
$22,000, and $11,000 for packers, swine
contractors, and live poultry dealers
respectively.
TABLE 19—ESTIMATED INDUSTRY TOTAL COSTS FOR THE SMALL BUSINESS EXCEPTION ALTERNATIVE
Packers
($)
Estimate type
lotter on DSK11XQN23PROD with PROPOSALS3
First-Year Costs ...............................................................................................
10 years Annualized at 3 Percent ...................................................................
10 years Annualized at 7 Percent ...................................................................
Ten-year costs annualized at 3 percent
would be $8,000 for packers, $3,000 for
swine contractors, and $1,000 for live
poultry dealers. This amounts to $24 for
each live poultry dealer, swine
contractor, and packer. Total ten-year
costs annualized at 3 percent would be
expected to be $12,000.
72,000
8,000
10,000
Ten-year costs annualized at 7 percent
would be $10,000 for packers, $3,000 for
swine contractors, and $1,000 for live
poultry dealers. This amounts to $28 for
each live poultry dealer, swine
contractor, and packer. Total ten-year
costs annualized at 3 percent would be
expected to be $14,000.
Swine
contractors
($)
22,000
3,000
3,000
20:25 Sep 30, 2022
Jkt 259001
PO 00000
Frm 00044
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
11,000
1,000
1,000
Packers
($)
105,000
12,000
14,000
Table 20 compares the average per
entity first-year costs of the Small
Business Exception Alternative to the
average revenue for each regulated small
business. First-year costs are
appropriate for a threshold analysis
because all of the costs associated with
the alternative would occur in the first
year.
179 $113.80 per hour × 1 hour of an attorney’s
time + 93.20 per hour × 1 hour of a manager’s time
= $207.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
Poultry
processors
($)
E:\FR\FM\03OCP3.SGM
03OCP3
Federal Register / Vol. 87, No. 190 / Monday, October 3, 2022 / Proposed Rules
60053
TABLE 20—COMPARISON OF PER ENTITY COST TO REVENUES FOR THE SMALL BUSINESS EXCEPTION ALTERNATIVE
Number of small
businesses
NAICS
112210—Swine Contractor ......................................................
311615—Poultry Processor .....................................................
311611—Meat Packer * ...........................................................
First-year costs
($)
108
54
346
207
207
207
Average revenue
or net sales per
Establishment
($)
485,860
50,729,044
83,356,860
First-year cost as
percent of
revenue
(percent)
0.0426
0.0004
0.0002
* Averages exclude net sales for packers that purchased less than $500,000 in livestock annually.
First-year costs as a percent of
revenues are small. Similar to proposed
§§ 201.304 and 201.306, relative costs
are highest for swine contractors
because average revenues for swine
contractors are considerably smaller
than average revenues for packers and
live poultry dealers. At 0.0426 percent,
the first-year cost to swine contractors is
small compared to revenue.
Average net sales for packers listed in
Table 18 have the same problem as the
net sales figures in Table 16. They
exclude the smallest packers, and
consequently the averages are biased
toward being too large. However, firstyear cost as a percent of net sales for
packers purchasing more than $500,000
per year is 0.0002 percent. Estimated
first year cost for each packer is $207.
Costs would be less than 0.1 percent of
revenues for any packer with revenue
greater than $20,700. Even for the
smallest packer that AMS regulates,
$207 would not likely have a significant
economic impact.
lotter on DSK11XQN23PROD with PROPOSALS3
Comparison of Alternatives
Expected costs for small businesses
under the Proposed Alternative’s
§§ 201.304 and 201.306 would be more
than double the expected costs for small
businesses under a Small Business
Exception Alternative. The cost
difference is due to recordkeeping
requirements. First-year costs would be
$128,000 more for the Proposed
Alternative than the Small Business
Exception Alternative. While all of the
costs associated with the Small Business
Exception Alternative occur in the first
year, small businesses would continue
to incur recordkeeping costs associated
with the Proposed Alternative
§§ 201.304 and 201.306 into the future.
Estimated costs annualized at 7 percent
are $104,000 higher for Proposed
Alternative §§ 201.304 and 201.306 than
for the Small Business Exemption
Alternative.
With either the Small Business
Exception Alternative, or the Proposed
Alternative, AMS expects the costs to be
relatively small. The number of
regulated entities that could experience
a cost increase is substantial. Most
VerDate Sep<11>2014
20:25 Sep 30, 2022
Jkt 259001
regulated packers and live poultry
dealers are small businesses. However,
AMS expects that few small businesses
would experience significant costs. For
all three groups of regulated entities:
packers, live poultry dealers, and swine
contractors, average first year costs are
expected to amount to less than one 0.1
percent of annual revenue for either of
the alternatives. AMS expects that any
additional costs to small packers, live
poultry dealers, and swine contractors
from this proposed rulemaking will not
change their ability to continue
operations or place any small businesses
at a competitive disadvantage.
AMS chose the Proposed Alternative’s
§§ 201.304 and 201.306 over the Small
Business Exception Alternative because
AMS wishes to prevent the kind of
undue prejudices and discrimination
described in the proposed rule. AMS
believes that keeping relevant records
serves as constant reminder to all
packers, live poultry dealers, and swine
contractors that they cannot purchase
livestock or enter into contracts for
growing services with the kind of undue
prejudices and discrimination described
in the rulemaking.
The Proposed Alternative’s §§ 201.304
and 201.306 are not expected to have a
significant economic impact on a
substantial number of small business
entities as defined in the Regulatory
Flexibility Act (5 U.S.C. 601 et seq.).
While confident in this assertion, AMS
acknowledges that individual
businesses may have relevant data to
supplement our analysis. AMS
encourages small stakeholders to submit
any relevant data during the comment
period.
E-Government Act
USDA is committed to complying
with the E-Government Act by
promoting the use of the internet and
other information technologies to
provide increased opportunities for
citizen access to Government
information and services, and for other
purposes.
PO 00000
Frm 00045
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
Executive Order 13175—Consultation
and Coordination With Indian Tribal
Governments
This proposed rule has been reviewed
in accordance with the requirements of
E.O. 13175—Consultation and
Coordination with Indian Tribal
governments. E.O. 13175 requires
Federal agencies to consult with tribes
on a government-to-government basis on
policies that have tribal implications,
including regulations, legislative
comments or proposed legislation, and
other policy statements or actions that
have substantial direct effects on one or
more Indian tribes, on the relationship
between the Federal Government and
Indian tribes or the distribution of
power and responsibilities between the
Federal Government and Indian tribes.
This proposed rule will impact
individual members of Indian Tribes
and will impact Tribal governments or
instrumentalities of Tribal governments.
The rulemaking will also impact the
relationship between Tribes and the
Federal Government. USDA will hold a
consultation with Tribal governments
regarding the impact of this proposed
rule with respect to Tribal governments
and Native American livestock
producers. USDA also seeks comments
and information from Tribal
organizations concerning impact on
individual American Indian/Alaska
Native livestock producers. Additional
details on the date and manner of the
consultations will be announced in a
‘‘Dear Tribal Leader Letter,’’ to be sent
individually to tribes and published on
the USDA Office of Tribal Relations
website at https://www.usda.gov/
tribalrelations/tribal-consultations.
Civil Rights Impact Analysis
AMS has considered the potential
civil rights implications of this
proposed rule on members of protected
groups to ensure that no person or group
would be adversely or
disproportionately at risk or
discriminated against on the basis of
race, color, national origin, gender,
religion, age, disability, sexual
orientation, marital or family status, or
protected genetic information. This
E:\FR\FM\03OCP3.SGM
03OCP3
60054
Federal Register / Vol. 87, No. 190 / Monday, October 3, 2022 / Proposed Rules
lotter on DSK11XQN23PROD with PROPOSALS3
rulemaking does not contain any
requirements related to eligibility,
benefits, or services that would have the
purpose or effect of excluding, limiting,
or otherwise disadvantaging any
individual, group, or class of persons on
one or more prohibited bases. In fact,
the proposed regulation would create
means by which AMS may be able to
address potential civil rights issues in
violation of the Act.
In its review, AMS conducted a
disparate impact analysis, using the
required calculations, which resulted in
a finding that Asian Americans,
American Indian/Alaskan Natives,
Pacific Islanders, and Native Hawaiians
were disproportionately impacted. AMS
analysis reflects that most producers
and poultry growers will experience
greater access to information regarding
acquiring, handling, and processing
quality livestock. The proposed
regulation provides clearer standards to
address market disadvantages to small
and medium scale producers and
growers, contributing to favorable
contract terms and equitable price
premiums.
AMS will institute enhance efforts to
notify the groups found to be more
significantly impacted of the regulations
and their implications. AMS outreach
will specifically target several
organizations that regularly engage with
or otherwise may represent the interests
of these impacted groups. As a result of
this outreach, if AMS detects the
possibility of the new regulation causing
a potential disparate impact on any
protected individual or group, AMS will
develop a mitigation strategy.
Executive Order 12988—Civil Justice
Reform
This proposed rule has been reviewed
under Executive Order 12988—Civil
Justice Reform. This proposed rule is
not intended to have retroactive effect.
This proposed rule would not preempt
state or local laws, regulations, or
policies, unless they present an
irreconcilable conflict with this
rulemaking. There are no administrative
procedures that must be exhausted prior
to any judicial challenge to the
provisions of this proposed rule.
Nothing in this proposed rule is
intended to interfere with a person’s
right to enforce liability against any
person subject to the Act under
authority granted in sec. 308 of the Act.
VI. Request for Comments
Comments submitted on or before
December 2, 2022 will be considered.
Comments should reference Docket No.
AMS–FTPP–21–0045 and the date and
page number of this issue of the Federal
VerDate Sep<11>2014
20:25 Sep 30, 2022
Jkt 259001
Register. Comments can be submitted
by either of the following methods:
• Federal eRulemaking Portal: Go to
https://www.regulations.gov. Enter
AMS–FTPP–21–0045 in the Search
filed. Select the Documents tab, then
select the Comment button in the list of
documents.
• Postal Mail/Commercial Delivery:
Send your comment to Docket No.
AMS–FTPP–21–0045, S. Brett Offutt,
Chief Legal Officer, Packers and
Stockyards Division, USDA, AMS,
FTPP; Room 2097–S, Mail Stop 3601,
1400 Independence Ave. SW,
Washington, DC 20250–3601.
List of Subjects in 9 CFR Part 201
Confidential business information,
Reporting and recordkeeping
requirements, Stockyards, Surety bonds,
Trade practices.
For the reasons set forth in the
preamble, AMS proposes to amend 9
CFR part 201 as follows:
PART 201—ADMINISTERING THE
PACKERS AND STOCKYARDS ACT
1. The authority citation for 9 CFR
part 201 continues to read as follows:
■
Authority: 7 U.S.C. 181–229c.
2. Add subpart O, consisting of
§§ 201.300 through 201.390, to read as
follows:
■
Subpart O—Competition and Market
Integrity
Sec.
201.300–201.301 [Reserved]
201.302 Definitions.
201.304 Undue prejudices or disadvantages
and unjust discriminatory practices.
201.306 Deceptive practices.
201.307–201.389 [Reserved]
201.390 Severability.
§§ 201.300–201.301
§ 201.302
[Reserved]
Definitions.
For purposes of this subpart, the
following definitions apply:
Covered producer means a livestock
producer as defined in this section or a
swine production contract grower or
poultry grower as defined in section 2(a)
of the Act (7 U.S.C. 182(8), (14)).
Livestock producer means any person
engaged in the raising and caring for
livestock by the producer or another
person, whether the livestock is owned
by the producer or by another person,
but not an employee of the owner of the
livestock.
Market vulnerable individual means a
person who is a member, or who a
regulated entity perceives to be a
member, of a group whose members
have been subjected to, or are at
PO 00000
Frm 00046
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
heightened risk of, adverse treatment
because of their identity as a member or
perceived member of the group without
regard to their individual qualities. A
market vulnerable individual includes a
company or organization where one or
more of the principal owners,
executives, or members would
otherwise be a market vulnerable
individual.
Regulated entity means a swine
contractor or live poultry dealer as
defined in section 2(a) of the Act (7
U.S.C. 182(8)) or a packer as defined in
section 201 of the Act (7 U.S.C. 191).
§ 201.304 Undue prejudices or
disadvantages and unjust discriminatory
practices.
(a) Prohibited bases. (1) A regulated
entity may not prejudice, disadvantage,
inhibit market access, or otherwise take
adverse action against a covered
producer with respect to any matter
related to livestock, meats, meat food
products, livestock products in
unmanufactured form, or live poultry
based upon the covered producer’s
status as a market vulnerable individual
or as a cooperative.
(2) Prejudice or disadvantage with
respect to paragraph (a)(1) of this
section includes the following actions:
(i) Offering contract terms that are less
favorable than those generally or
ordinarily offered.
(ii) Refusing to deal.
(iii) Differential contract performance
or enforcement.
(iv) Termination of a contract or nonrenewal of a contract.
(b) Retaliation prohibited. (1) A
regulated entity may not retaliate or
otherwise take an adverse action against
a covered producer because of the
covered producer’s participation in the
activities described in paragraph (b)(2)
of this section to the extent that these
activities are not otherwise prohibited
by Federal or state law, including
antitrust laws.
(2) The following activities are
protected under paragraph (b)(1) of this
section:
(i) A covered producer communicates
with a government agency with respect
to any matter related to livestock, meats,
meat food products, livestock products
in unmanufactured form, or live poultry
or petitions for redress of grievances
before a court, legislature, or
government agency.
(ii) A covered producer asserts any of
the rights granted under the Act or this
part, or asserts contract rights.
(iii) A covered producer asserts the
right to form or join a producer or
grower association or organization, or to
collectively process, prepare for market,
handle, or market livestock or poultry.
E:\FR\FM\03OCP3.SGM
03OCP3
Federal Register / Vol. 87, No. 190 / Monday, October 3, 2022 / Proposed Rules
lotter on DSK11XQN23PROD with PROPOSALS3
(iv) A covered producer
communicates or cooperates with a
person for the purposes of improving
production or marketing of livestock or
poultry.
(v) A covered producer communicates
or negotiates with a regulated entity for
the purpose of exploring a business
relationship.
(vi) A covered producer supports or
participates as a witness in any
proceeding under the Act, or a
proceeding that relates to an alleged
violation of law by a regulated entity.
(3) For purposes of paragraph (b)(1) of
this section, retaliation includes the
following actions:
(i) Termination of contracts or nonrenewal of contracts.
(ii) Adversely differential
performance or enforcement of a
contract.
(iii) Refusing to deal with a covered
producer.
(iv) Interference in farm real estate
transactions or contracts with third
parties.
(c) Recordkeeping of compliance
practices. (1) The regulated entity shall
retain all records relevant to its
compliance with paragraphs (a) and (b)
of this section for no less than 5 years
from the date of record creation.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
20:25 Sep 30, 2022
Jkt 259001
(2) Records that may be relevant
under paragraph (c)(1) of this section
include, if any, policies and procedures,
staff training materials, materials
informing covered producers regarding
reporting mechanisms and protections,
compliance testing, board of directors’
oversight materials, and the number and
nature of complaints received relevant
to this section.
§ 201.306
Deceptive practices.
(a) Prohibited practices. A regulated
entity may not engage in the specific
deceptive practices prohibited in
paragraphs (b) through (e) of this section
with respect to any matter related to
livestock, meats, meat food products,
livestock products in unmanufactured
form, or live poultry.
(b) Contract formation. A regulated
entity may not make or modify a
contract by employing a pretext, false or
misleading statement, or omission of
material fact necessary to make a
statement not false or misleading.
(c) Contract performance. A regulated
entity may not perform under or enforce
a contract by employing a pretext, false
or misleading statement, or omission of
material fact necessary to make a
statement not false or misleading.
PO 00000
Frm 00047
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 9990
60055
(d) Contract termination. A regulated
entity may not terminate a contract or
take any other adverse action against a
covered producer by employing a
pretext, false or misleading statement, or
omission of material fact necessary to
make a statement not false or
misleading.
(e) Contract refusal. A regulated entity
may not provide false or misleading
information to a covered producer or
association of covered producers
concerning a refusal to contract.
§§ 201.307–201.389
§ 201.390
[Reserved]
Severability.
If any provision of this subpart is
declared invalid or the applicability
thereof to any person or circumstances
is held invalid, the validity of the
remainder of this subpart or the
applicability thereof to other persons or
circumstances shall not be affected
thereby.
Erin Morris,
Associate Administrator, Agricultural
Marketing Service.
[FR Doc. 2022–21114 Filed 9–30–22; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 3410–02–P
E:\FR\FM\03OCP3.SGM
03OCP3
Agencies
[Federal Register Volume 87, Number 190 (Monday, October 3, 2022)]
[Proposed Rules]
[Pages 60010-60055]
From the Federal Register Online via the Government Publishing Office [www.gpo.gov]
[FR Doc No: 2022-21114]
[[Page 60009]]
Vol. 87
Monday,
No. 190
October 3, 2022
Part IV
Department of Agriculture
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
Agricultural Marketing Service
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
9 CFR Part 201
Inclusive Competition and Market Integrity Under the Packers and
Stockyards Act; Proposed Rule
Federal Register / Vol. 87 , No. 190 / Monday, October 3, 2022 /
Proposed Rules
[[Page 60010]]
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
DEPARTMENT OF AGRICULTURE
Agricultural Marketing Service
9 CFR Part 201
[Doc. No. AMS-FTPP-21-0045]
RIN 0581-AE05
Inclusive Competition and Market Integrity Under the Packers and
Stockyards Act
AGENCY: Agricultural Marketing Service, Department of Agriculture
(USDA).
ACTION: Proposed rule.
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
SUMMARY: The U.S. Department of Agriculture's (USDA) Agricultural
Marketing Service (AMS) is soliciting comments on proposed revisions to
the regulations under the Packers and Stockyards Act, 1921. The
proposal would prohibit certain prejudices against market-vulnerable
individuals that tend to exclude or disadvantage covered producers in
those markets. The proposal would identify retaliatory practices that
interfere with lawful communications, assertion of rights, and
associational participation, among other protected activities, as
unjust discrimination prohibited by the law. The proposal would also
identify unlawfully deceptive practices that violate the Packers and
Stockyards Act with respect to contract formation, contract
performance, contract termination, and contract refusal. The purpose of
the rule is to promote inclusive competition and market integrity in
the livestock, meats, poultry, and live poultry markets.
DATES: Comments must be received by December 2, 2022.
ADDRESSES: Comments must be submitted through the Federal e-rulemaking
portal at https://www.regulations.gov and should reference the document
number and the date and page number of this issue of the Federal
Register. AMS strongly prefers comments be submitted electronically.
However, written comments may be submitted (i.e., postmarked) via mail
to S. Brett Offutt, Chief Legal Officer, Packers and Stockyards
Division, USDA, AMS, FTPP; Room 2097-S, Mail Stop 3601, 1400
Independence Ave. SW, Washington, DC 20250-3601. All comments submitted
in response to this proposed rule will be included in the record and
will be made available to the public. Please be advised that the
identity of individuals or entities submitting comments will be made
public on the internet at the address provided above. Parties who wish
to comment anonymously may do so by entering ``N/A'' in the fields that
would identify the commenter.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: S. Brett Offutt, Chief Legal Officer/
Policy Advisor, Packers and Stockyards Division, USDA AMS Fair Trade
Practices Program, 1400 Independence Ave. SW, Washington, DC 20250;
Phone: (202) 690-4355; or email: [email protected].
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION:
Outline of the Notice of Proposed Rulemaking
I. Introduction (Statutory Authority)
A. Background to This Rulemaking
B. Previous Rulemakings
II. Undue Prejudices or Disadvantages and Discriminatory Practices
A. Agency Interpretation of Undue or Unreasonable Prejudice or
Disadvantage and Unjust Discriminatory Practices
B. Prohibited Undue Prejudices or Disadvantages and Unjust
Discrimination--Proposed Sec. 201.304(a)(1)--Generally
i. Authority Provided by the Act
ii. Economic Rationale
iii. Specific Proposed Protected Bases
C. Cooperatives--Proposed Sec. 201.304(a)(2)
D. Enumerated Undue Prejudices
E. Retaliation
i. Retaliation as Discrimination Under the Act
ii. Economic Rationale
F. Prohibition on Retaliation--Proposed Sec. 201.304(b)
G. Bases of Protected Activities--Proposed Sec. 201.304(b).
i. Assertion of Rights
ii. Associational Participation
iii. Lawful Communications
H. Delineation of Protected Activities
I. Recordkeeping--Proposed Sec. 201.304(c)
J. Request for Comments
III. Deceptive Practices
A. Scope of Deceptive Practices Regulated
B. Deceptive Practices in the Formation of Contract
C. Deceptive Practices in the Operation of Contract
D. Deceptive Practices in the Termination of Contract
E. Deceptive Practices in Refusal To Deal
F. Request for Comments
IV. Severability
V. Required Regulatory Analyses
VI. Request for Comments
I. Introduction and Regulatory Background
The rise of vertically integrated contract agriculture and highly
concentrated local markets in livestock and poultry over the last four
decades have increasingly left many producers and growers (hereinafter
producers, unless otherwise noted) vulnerable to a range of practices
that unjustly exclude them from and undermine their economic
opportunities in the marketplace. The regulatory toolkit embodied in
the Packers & Stockyards Act, as amended (P&S Act or Act) (7 U.S.C. 181
et seq.), has not been deployed to keep pace with these issues. AMS is
proposing this regulation to enhance those basic protections that
modern livestock and poultry producers need to promote inclusive
competition and market integrity. We invite comment on a range of
questions in this proposal.
Specifically, AMS is proposing to:
Prohibit, as undue prejudices, disadvantages, and adverse
actions against ``market vulnerable individuals'' who are at heightened
risk in relevant markets;
Prohibit, as unjust discrimination, retaliatory and
adverse actions that interfere with lawful communications, assertion of
rights, associational participation, and other protected activities;
Prohibit, as deceptive practices, regulated entities
employing pretexts, false or misleading statements, or omissions of
material facts, in contract formation, contract performance, contract
termination, and contract refusal; and
Require recordkeeping to support USDA monitoring,
evaluation, and enforcement of compliance with aspects of this rule.
AMS is proposing these modernized regulations under the Act's
provisions prohibiting undue prejudice, unjust discrimination, and
deception to provide for clearer, more effective standards to govern
the modern marketplace and to better protect, through compliance and
enforcement, individually harmed producers and growers. Enacted in 1921
``to comprehensively regulate packers, stockyards, marketing agents and
dealers,'' \1\ the P&S Act, among other things, prohibits actions that
hinder integrity and competition in the livestock and poultry markets.
Section 202(a) of the Act states that it is unlawful for any packer,
swine contractor, or live poultry dealer to engage in or use any
unfair, unjustly discriminatory, or deceptive practice or device.\2\
Section 202(b) of the Act states that it is unlawful for any packer,
swine contractor, or live poultry dealer to make or give any undue or
unreasonable preference or advantage to any particular person or
locality, or subject any particular person or locality to any undue or
unreasonable prejudice or disadvantage in any respect. The Secretary of
Agriculture (Secretary) has
[[Page 60011]]
delegated the responsibility for administering the P&S Act to AMS.
Within AMS, the Packers, and Stockyards Division (PSD) of the Fair-
Trade Practices Program has responsibility for the day-to-day
administration of the P&S Act. The current regulations implementing the
P&S Act are found in title 9, part 201 of the Code of Federal
Regulations (CFR). Section 407 of the P&S Act (7 U.S.C. 228) provides
that the Secretary ``may make such rules, regulations, and orders as
may be necessary to carry out the provisions of this Act.'' This
proposed rule, if finalized, would amend 9 CFR part 201.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1\ Hays Livestock Comm'n Co. v. Maly Livestock Comm'n Co., 498
F.2d 925, 927 (10th Cir. 1974).
\2\ 7 U.S.C. 192(a).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
A. Background to This Rulemaking
Congress enacted the P&S Act after many years of concern about
farmers and ranchers being cheated and mistreated. At the time,
Congress worried that the five very large meatpackers' control over the
nation's food supply tended toward monopolization, which could put
economic opportunity for producers and their communities at risk,
destroying individual economic opportunity for producers and smaller
food businesses and harming rural communities, among other harms.\3\
Moreover, Congress believed that existing antitrust and market
regulatory laws, including the Sherman Act and Federal Trade Commission
Act, did not sufficiently protect farmers and ranchers.\4\ Accordingly,
in the P&S Act, Congress gave the Secretary of Agriculture broad
authority to regulate the meatpacking industry. The House of
Representatives' report on the P&S Act stated that it was the ``most
comprehensive measure and extends farther than any previous law in the
regulation of private business, in time of peace, except possibly the
interstate commerce act.'' \5\ The Conference Report on the P&S Act
stated that: ``Congress intends to exercise, in the bill, the fullest
control of the packers and stockyards which the Constitution permits .
. .'' \6\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\3\ See 61 Cong. Rec. 1860 (1921) (House Floor Debate).
\4\ See, Shively, J. and Roberts, J., ``Competition Under the
Packers and Stockyards Act: What Now?'' 15 Drake Journal of
Agricultural Law 419, 422-423 (2010); and Current Legislation, 22
Columbia Law Review 68, 69 (1922).
\5\ House Report No. 67-77, at 2 (1921).
\6\ House Report No. 67-324, at 3 (1921).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
In the early 1900s, meat packing in the United States was highly
concentrated, with approximately 50 to 70 percent of the beef packing
industry controlled by the industry's ``Big Five:'' Armour, Cudahy,
Morris, Swift, and Wilson.\7\ A 1918 Federal Trade Commission (FTC)
meat industry investigation found that in 1916 the Big Five controlled
the slaughter and processing of 82 percent of cattle, 79 percent of
calves, 87 percent of sheep, and 63 percent of swine in the U.S.\8\
Those five dominant operators also controlled an interlocking network
of the feed mills, stockyards, and transportation infrastructure that
supported the industry. As extensively documented in a report by the
FTC, which set the stage for Congressional passage of the P&S Act,
those five packers deployed from their positions in that market
structure a range of practices to further entrench their dominance.\9\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\7\ Mathews, K. H. Jr., W. F. Hahn, K. E. Nelson, L. A. Duewer,
and R. A. Gustafson. April 1999. U.S. Beef Industry: Cattle Cycles,
Price Spreads, and Packer Concentration. U.S. Department of
Agriculture, Market and Trade Economics Division, Economic Research
Service. Technical Bulletin No. 1874.
\8\ Federal Trade Commission. 1918. Annual Report for 1918, p.
23., available at ftc_ar_1918.pdf (last accessed 8/9/2022).
\9\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
At that same time, the Department of Justice (DOJ) brought
enforcement cases under the Sherman Act against the packing industry,
which resulted in a series of consent decrees (judicially overseen
agreements) that restructured the market.\10\ The consent decrees,
together with the adoption of the P&S Act, reformed market practices by
eliminating packer ownership of cattle and their means of transporting
it, and reinforced market structures that--for a period of time in the
20th century--secured open, fair marketplaces for all, such as terminal
auction yards regulated as stockyards by the Packers and Stockyards
Administration of USDA.\11\ By 1963, the four-firm concentration ratio
(the standard economic tool used to evaluate the degree of
concentration in markets) had fallen to 26 percent in beef and 33
percent in hogs.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\10\ United States v. Swift & Co., Equity No. 37623, (Sup. Ct.
of D.C. 1920).
\11\ Harl, Agricultural Law, sec. 71.03 (1993).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Amidst slowing demand in the beef and hog sectors, the dramatic
growth of demand in the poultry industry, technological advances and
increased returns to scale in meat processing, and a decline in Federal
antitrust and fair markets enforcement, concentration returned to the
meat packing industry.\12\ Between 1980 and 2020, the four-firm
concentration ratio grew from 36 percent to 81 percent in beef packing
(steers and heifers) and rose by 34 percent to 64 percent in hogs.\13\
Between 1977 and 2020, the four-firm concentration ratio in the poultry
broiler industry increased from 22 percent to 53 percent.\14\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\12\ MacDonald, J.M., M. E. Ollinger, K. E. Nelson, and C. R.
Handy. Consolidation in U.S. Meatpacking. Food and Rural Economics
Division, Economic Research Service, U.S. Department of Agriculture.
Agricultural Economic Report No. 785. Available at https://www.ers.usda.gov/publications/pub-details/?pubid=41120, accessed 9/
19/22.
\13\ U.S. Department of Agriculture, Agricultural Marketing
Service., Packers and Stockyards Division, Annual Report. Various
years.
\14\ U.S. Department of Agriculture, Agricultural Marketing
Service, Packers and Stockyards Division, Annual Report, 2020. 2021
draft pending as of 07/11/22. United States Department of
Agriculture Grain Inspection, Packers and Stockyards Administration.
``Assessment of the Livestock and Poultry Industries Fiscal Year
2007.'' May 2008.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The above data reflects the state of concentration nationally, but
concentration in local markets that exceeds national averages has been
observed in the poultry, hog and pig, and cattle industries. In the
last available survey of local markets (2011), MacDonald and Key found
that about one quarter of contract growers reported that there was just
one live poultry dealer in their area; another quarter reported two;
another quarter reported three; and the rest reported four or more.\15\
Regional concentration is often higher than national concentration for
hogs.\16\ And in cattle, based on AMS's experience conducting
investigations and monitoring markets, there are commonly only one or
two buyers in some local geographic markets, and few sellers have the
option of selling fed cattle to more than three or four packers.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\15\ MacDonald, James M. ``Technology, Organization, and
Financial Performance in U.S. Broiler Production,'' EIB-126, U.S.
Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service, June 2014.
\16\ Wise, T. A., S. E. Trist. ``Buyer Power in U.S. Hog
Markets: A Critical Review of the Literature,'' Tufts University,
Global Development and Environment Institute (GDAE) Working Paper
No. 10-04, August 2010, available at: https://sites.tufts.edu/gdae/files/2020/03/10-04HogBuyerPower.pdf.TAbl (last accessed 8/9/2022).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The move towards heightened concentration was accompanied by a
dramatic shift from the spot market towards various types of vertical
contracts. In the early 20th century, farm-finished cattle and hogs
were primarily shipped by rail and slaughtered in urban centers close
to large consumer bases, and fresh meat was rail-shipped only by the
largest packers. Prices for cattle and hog purchases were largely
negotiated in spot, cash markets in person. In 1921, poultry
consumption accounted for a small share of total U.S. meat consumption,
and retail distribution outlets (i.e., local food markets) were not
centralized.
[[Page 60012]]
In successive decades, as concentration in the industry increased
and as the size of plants increased, large packers needed to ensure
constant and secure supplies of animals to keep these larger plants
running at peak capacity.\17\ Buying animals through contracts with
producers was believed to facilitate their ability to do so. Vertical
contracts took the form of production, marketing, and forward
contracts.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\17\ MacDonald. J. M. and W. D. McBride. The Transformation of
U.S. Livestock Agriculture: Scale, Efficiency, and Risks. January
2009. Economic Information Bulletin No. (EIB-43). Available at
https://www.ers.usda.gov/webdocs/publications/44292/10992_eib43.pdf?v=0, accessed 9-20-2022.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Livestock and poultry production contracts are agreements between a
producer and a contractor, where the livestock (generally hogs) or
poultry are grown by a grower on behalf of the contractor under
specific guidelines (production practices or target weight, for
example) identified in the contract. The producer is generally paid a
contract fee by the contractor for growing the livestock or poultry.
Once the livestock or poultry reach a specific weight, they are often
marketed to a packer or live poultry dealer under a marketing contract,
though they could also be marketed on the spot market. Under a
marketing contract, the ownership of the livestock or poultry (mostly
livestock) remains with the producer until they are ready to be
marketed to a packer or live poultry dealer. A marketing contract is an
agreement between a producer and a packer or live poultry dealer that
identifies a price (or a pricing formula), quantities/qualities, and a
delivery schedule for the livestock or poultry to the packer or live
poultry dealer. A forward contract is a specific type of marketing
contract (generally for livestock) under which a specific group of
livestock is negotiated for sale by a producer or contractor to a
packer several months in advance of delivery of the livestock. The
producer or contractor and packer agree to the delivery month and
pricing method for the specific group of livestock to be delivered. The
producer generally picks the day of delivery in the delivery month.
The growth of these vertical contract relationships, in the context
of highly concentrated markets, has led to concerns that firms have
greater control over producers and thus have more ability to abuse
their market power, impede producer choices, exclude some market
participants, and coerce producers unwittingly into inefficient farm
decisions.\18\ Many have expressed concern that the decline in the use
of spot markets to market livestock has also led to harder-to-quantify
losses of independent ways of life, adversely impacting rural economies
and communities.\19\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\18\ Hendrickson, M.K., and H.S. James, Jr. 2005. ``The Ethics
of Constrained Choice: How the Industrialization of Agriculture
Impacts Farming and Farmer Behavior.'' Journal of Agricultural and
Environmental Ethics, 18: 269-291. In: Hendrickson, M., James, H.,
Heffernan, W.D. 2013. ``Vertical Integration and Concentration in
U.S. Agriculture.'' In: Thompson, P., Kaplan, D. (eds) Encyclopedia
of Food and Agricultural Ethics. Springer, Dordrecht, 7. See also
Christopher Leonard, ``The Meat Racket'' (2015); C. Robert Taylor,
``Harvested Cattle, Slaughtered Markets,'' April 27, 2022, available
at https://www.antitrustinstitute.org/work-product/aai-advisor-robert-taylor-issues-new-analysis-on-the-market-power-problem-in-beef-lays-out-new-policy-framework-for-ensuring-competition-and-fairness-in-cattle-and-beef-markets/; Peter Carstensen, ``Buyer
Power and the Horizontal Merger Guidelines: Minor Progress on an
Important Issue,'' 14 U. Pa. J. Bus. L. 775 (2012), available at
https://repository.law.wisc.edu/s/uwlaw/item/29746.
\19\ James, H.S. Jr., M.K. Hendrickson, and P.H. Howard. 2013.
``Networks, Power and Dependency in the Agrifood Industry.'' In H.S.
James, Jr. (ed.), ``The Ethics and Economics of Agrifood
Competition'' (pp. 99-126). Dordrecht, The Netherlands: Springer
Publishers. In: Hendrickson, M., James, H., Heffernan, W.D. 2013.
``Vertical Integration and Concentration in US Agriculture.'' In:
Thompson, P., Kaplan, D. (eds) Encyclopedia of Food and Agricultural
Ethics. Springer, Dordrecht, 8.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Among the four major meat markets, chicken companies adopted
production contracting earliest and most completely. Between 1950 and
1955, along with increased vertical integration through ownership of
the flocks, the use of production contracts rose from 5 to 85 percent
of the broiler industry's production to become nearly universal by
1975. The same switch was slower in turkey production, exceeding 80
percent in 1977.\20\ The share of hogs sold through long-term marketing
contracts increased from 10 to 72 percent between 1993 and 2001.
Packer-owned hogs increased from 6.4 percent of U.S. hog production in
1994 to 24 percent in 2000.\21\ Comparatively, in the cattle industry
32 percent of production was under contract in 2013--referring again to
contractual agreements for growing cattle to a certain weight or under
a certain production method.22 23 Marketing contracts have
seen far greater adoption. Cattle being marketed through forward
contracts and Alternative Marketing Arrangements (AMAs), where cattle
are already dedicated to certain packers or end-buyers, have risen from
about 35 percent in 2005 to 73 percent today.\24\ As a result, since
2005, negotiated cash trades have declined from 65 percent to about 27
percent today.\25\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\20\ Martinez, S. W. (2002). ``Vertical Coordination of
Marketing Systems: Lessons From the Poultry, Egg, and Pork
Industries.'' (No. 1473-2016-120694) Economic Research Service,
USDA, Washington, DC.
\21\ Martinez, S. W. (2002). ``Vertical Coordination of
Marketing Systems: Lessons From the Poultry, Egg, and Pork
Industries'' (No. 1473-2016-120694) Economic Research Service, USDA,
Washington, DC.
\22\ Crespi, John, and Tina L. Saitone. (2018) ``Are Cattle
Markets the Last Frontier? Vertical Coordination in Animal-Based
Procurement Markets.'' Annual Review of Resource Economics 10(1):
207-227.
\23\ Macdonald, James M. (2015) ``Trends in Agricultural
Contracts.'' Choices 30(3):1-6.
\24\ Packers and Stockyards Division, ``Annual Report'' (2020).
\25\ U.S. Department of Agriculture, Agricultural Marketing
Service, Market News, as of May 2022.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Some of these developments were driven in part by technological and
marketing changes.\26\ In cattle, for example, the development of boxed
beef to ship standardized cuts allowed packers to move their slaughter
facilities closer to producers. With cattle no longer shipped from
terminal auction markets to the large cities, packers played a more
dominant role in the procurement of cattle directly from producers
within a surrounding area, and marketing practices shifted, for a time,
towards bilateral cash negotiation and, then eventually, longer-term
marketing contracts with pricing formulas.\27\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\26\ Lonergan, S. M., and D. N. Marple. ``Historical
perspectives of the meat and animal industry and their relationship
to animal growth, body composition, and meat technology,'' ``The
Science of Animal Growth and Meat Technology.'' Lonergan, S. M., D.
N. Marple, Eds., Second Edition, Elsevier, (2019) 1-17, available at
The Science of Animal Growth and Meat Technology [verbar]
ScienceDirect.
\27\ Lawrence, J.D., Schroeder, T.C. and Hayenga, M.L. (2001),
``Evolving Producer-Packer-Customer Linkages in the Beef and Pork
Industries.'' Applied Economic Perspectives and Policy, 23: 370-385.
Available at https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-9353.00067.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
[[Page 60013]]
The increased use of long-term production and marketing contracts
in livestock and poultry markets, can foster greater vertical
coordination, and potentially allows certain production and marketing
efficiencies related to scale and certain enhanced aspects of packer,
or even retailer, control over product differentiation. The use of
vertical contracts may be appealing to livestock or poultry producers
for a range of reasons, including more secure access to markets. In
poultry markets, for example, contracts shift some aspects of market
risks from producers to live poultry dealers, such as grain prices or
certain weather-related risks.\28\ In the case of livestock, contracts
can also reduce a producer's output price risk.\29\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\28\ Knoeber, Charles R., and Walter N. Thurman. (1995) ``Don't
Count Your Chickens. . . : Risk and Risk Shifting in the Broiler
Industry.'' American Journal of Agricultural Economics 77(3): 486-
496.
\29\ Key, N. and MacDonald, J.M. (2006) ``Agricultural
Contracting: Trading Autonomy for Risk Reduction'' Amber Waves, U.S.
Department of Agriculture Economic Research Service. https://www.ers.usda.gov/amber-waves/2006/february/agricultural-contracting-trading-autonomy-for-risk-reduction/
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
On the other hand, as they facilitate packers and live poultry
dealers' control across the supply chain, contracts can shift certain
risks onto or between producers.\30\ In particular, without robust open
spot markets, cattle producers have complained of less ability to enter
the markets and less competition between buyers for better prices.\31\
As one notable commentator has termed them, these markets appear to be
by ``invitation only.'' \32\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\30\ See, e.g., Michael Kades, ``Protecting Livestock Producers
and Chicken Growers,'' Washington Center for Equitable Growth (May
5, 2022), available at https://equitablegrowth.org/research-paper/protecting-livestock-producers-and-chicken-growers/; Mary K.
Hendrickson, et al., ``The Food System: Concentration and Its
Impacts,'' A Special Report for Farm Family Action Alliance, May
2021, available at https://farmaction.us/concentrationreport/; C.
Robert Taylor, ``Harvested Cattle, Slaughtered Markets,'' April 27,
2022, available at https://www.antitrustinstitute.org/work-product/aai-advisor-robert-taylor-issues-new-analysis-on-the-market-power-problem-in-beef-lays-out-new-policy-framework-for-ensuring-competition-and-fairness-in-cattle-and-beef-markets/; Peter
Carstensen, ``Buyer Power and the Horizontal Merger Guidelines:
Minor Progress on an Important Issue,'' 14 U. Pa. J. Bus. L. 775
(2012), available at https://repository.law.wisc.edu/s/uwlaw/item/29746.
\31\ See, e.g., Bill Bullard, ``Chronically Besieged: The U.S.
Live Cattle Industry,'' Presentation to Thurman Arnold Project at
Yale and Law, Ethics, & Animals Program at Yale Law School, ``Big Ag
& Antitrust Conference,'' Jan. 2021, available at https://www.r-calfusa.com/wp-content/uploads/2021/01/210116-Chronically-Beseiged-The-U.S.-Live-Cattle-Industry-Final.pdf; see also Nathan Miller et
al., ``Buyer Power in the Beef Packing Industry: An Update on
Research in Progress,'' April 2022, available at https://www.nathanhmiller.org/cattlemarkets.pdf.
\32\ C. Robert Taylor, ``The Many Faces of Corporate Power in
the Food System.'' Presented at DOJ/FTC Workshop on Merger
Enforcement, February 2004, available at https://www.justice.gov/atr/many-faces-power-food-system.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Limited options for producers heighten the risks of prejudicial
exclusion and retaliation. Over the years, these concerns have been
reported to USDA, but the Department has not been able to effectively
address complaints, in part owing to insufficient clarity around P&S
Act rules and standards and related questions around the ability for
individuals to bring cases based on specific instances of harm.
The rise of concentrated and vertically integrated markets also
gives rise to certain abuses that may take the form of deception. For
example, cattle producers have complained to USDA that they are
provided with false pretexts as to why a packer would not accept cattle
from a producer or would pay less for it. Similarly, poultry and swine
growers have complained they have not been told the truth regarding why
they were terminated from contracts or otherwise treated differently
under them. These forms of deception may also be connected with efforts
to discriminate, retaliate, or otherwise unjustly exclude certain
producers or growers from the marketplace.\33\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\33\ See, e.g., ``Transition Recommendations: On Issues Related
to Agricultural Concentration and Competition,'' Campaign for
Contract Agriculture Reform . . . Western Organization of Resource
Councils, et al., Nov. 9, 2020.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Concerns with the rise of vertically integrated contracting across
concentrated markets were highlighted in a series of workshops
conducted by the U.S. Department of Justice (DOJ) and USDA in 2010.\34\
And indeed, following the workshops, a number of producers reported to
USDA that they suffered retaliation, and that racial and other
exclusionary prejudices were problems. In 2010 and 2016, USDA proposed
regulations seeking to address many of these concerns, given their
pervasiveness in the marketplace and the longstanding challenges that
USDA faced in addressing them. However, the relevant provisions of the
proposed regulations were not finalized.\35\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\34\ Department of Justice. ``Competition and Agriculture:
Voices from the Workshops on Agriculture and Antitrust Enforcement
in our 21st Century Economy and Thoughts on the Way Forward.'' May
2012. Available at https://www.justice.gov/sites/default/files/atr/legacy/2012/05/16/283291.pdf.
\35\ Poultry Grower Ranking Systems; Withdrawal of Proposed
Rule, 86 FR 60779 (November 4, 2021).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Unfortunately, the concentrated nature of livestock and poultry
markets exposes all producers to potential market abuses, but some may
not be well positioned to protect themselves. Racial and ethnic
minorities are arguably more exposed to market abuses, as evidenced by
their participation in the agricultural sector having declined sharply
over the last many decades. The most recent data from the 2017 Census
of Agriculture (Figures 1 and 2) indicate that non-white racial and
ethnic groups constitute a very small share of contracted livestock and
poultry producers--a trend likely due in part to historical
discrimination against these groups.
Undoubtedly, discrimination such as what has been experienced by
these groups in the past continues in some form today, which is why
additional protections are needed. Further, the same USDA Census of
Agriculture data show that producers who identify as Black and Native
Hawaiian are more likely to have lower gross revenue than their white
counterparts, which makes these producers relatively more vulnerable to
the market abuses observed in the sector today. These longstanding
challenges have prompted Congress and USDA to promote more equitable
market access. Section II.B.ii, below provides a more extensive
discussion of AMS's concerns regarding the exclusion from, or
disadvantages in, certain markets.
Retaliation remains a prevalent concern in today's concentrated and
highly integrated markets. For example, as recently as April 2022,
threats and fear of retaliation interfered with plans for invited
witnesses to testify at each of the House and Senate Agriculture
Committees' hearings on livestock competition practices. In his opening
remarks, House Agriculture Committee Chair David Scott noted:
We were supposed to have a 4th witness, a rancher, on our panel,
but due to intimidation and threats to this person's livelihood, to
this person's reputation, they chose not to participate out of fear.
Witness intimidation is unacceptable. . .
Only a day before, Senator Deborah Fischer had stated:
I wish we had a Nebraska producer here, but as is noted in their
letter, none of our producer members we encouraged to testify were
willing to put themselves out front for fear of possible retribution
from other market participants, an unfortunate reality of today's
cattle industry.\36\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\36\ House Chair David Scott D-GA, Opening remarks, U.S. House,
Committee on Agriculture, ``An Examination of Price Discrepancies,
Transparency, and Alleged Unfair Practices in Cattle Markets,''
April 27, 2022, (14 min: 24 sec), available at https://anchor.fm/houseagdems/episodes/An-Examination-of-Price-Discrepancies-Transparency-and-Alleged-Unfair-Practices-in-Cattle-Markets-e1hpvo8/a-a7r40dk. U.S. Senate Committee on Agriculture, Nutrition, and
Forestry, ``Legislative hearing to review S. 4030, the Cattle Price
Discovery and Transparency Act of 2022, and S. 3870, the Meat and
Poultry Special Investigator Act of 2022,'' April 26, 2022 (1 hour
39 min), available at https://www.agriculture.senate.gov/hearings/legislative-hearing-to-review-s-4030-the-cattle-price-discovery-and-transparency-act-of-2022-and-s3870-the-meat-and-poultry-special-investigator-act-of-2022.
[[Page 60014]]
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Producer organizations have also recently reported to USDA concerns
relating to possible coercion in the rulemaking comment process.\37\
Section II, and in particular II.E.ii, below, provide a more fulsome
discussion of concerns regarding retaliation for engaging in protected
activities.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\37\ See, e.g., U.S. Department of Agriculture, ``USDA Extends
Public Comment Period to August 23 and Posts Public Webinar for the
Proposed Rule to Promote Transparency in Poultry Grower Contracting
and Tournaments,'' Aug. 5, 2022, available at https://www.usda.gov/media/press-releases/2022/08/05/usda-extends-public-comment-period-august-23-and-posts-public (last accessed Aug. 2022).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Deception in various forms and guises also remains a concern in the
marketplace, including during the COVID-19 pandemic, where producers
had dramatically reduced access to markets.\38\ We discuss these
concerns extensively in Section III, below.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\38\ On limits to market access in the pandemic, see U.S.
Department of Agriculture, Agricultural Marketing Service,
``Agricultural Competition: A Plan in Support of Fair and
Competitive Markets,'' May 2022, available at https://www.ams.usda.gov/reports/agricultural-competition-plan-support-fair-and-competitive-markets (last accessed Aug. 2022).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The historic Executive order issued by the Biden-Harris
administration, Executive Order (E.O.) 14036--Promoting Competition in
the American Economy (86 FR 36987; July 9, 2021), directs the Secretary
of Agriculture to address unfair treatment of farmers and improve
conditions of competition in their markets by considering rulemaking to
address, among other things, certain practices related to market abuses
and enhanced competition in the livestock, poultry, and related
markets, including unjustly discriminatory, unduly prejudicial, and
deceptive practices, in particular retaliation. E.O. 14036 also
underscored that an individual should not have to show market-wide harm
to secure relief under the Act. AMS has considered that direction in
undertaking this rulemaking.
The P&S Act is a remedial statute enacted to address problems faced
by farmers, producers, and other participants in certain livestock,
poultry, and related agricultural markets; to protect the public from
predatory practices; and to help ensure a stable food supply. Thus, as
academics and courts have noted, the Act has ``tort-like provisions
that are concerned with unfair practices and discrimination'' that
fulfill a ``market facilitating function,'' which Congress designed to
prevent ``market abuse.'' \39\ AMS interprets and implements the Act to
affect its core statutory purposes.\40\ AMS is concerned that the
current regulations do not adequately address many unduly prejudicial,
unjustly discriminatory, and deceptive practices, which are exacerbated
by increased horizontal concentration and vertical contracting. This
proposed rule aims to address those concerns.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\39\ Herbert Hovenkamp, ``Does the Packers and Stockyards Act
Require Antitrust Harm?'' (2011). Faculty Scholarship at Penn Carey
Law. 1862. https://scholarship.law.upenn.edu/faculty_scholarship/1862 (``subsections (a) and (b) appear to be tort-like provisions
that are concerned with unfair practices and discrimination, but not
with restraint of trade or monopoly as such''); Peter Carstensen,
The Packers and Stockyards Act: A History of Failure to Date, CPI
Antitrust Journal 2-7 (April 2010) (``Congress sought to ensure that
the practices of buyers and sellers in livestock (and later poultry)
markets were fair, reasonable, and transparent. This goal can best
be described as market facilitating regulation.''); Michael C. Stumo
& Douglas J. O'Brien, Antitrust Unfairness vs. Equitable Unfairness
in Farmer/Meat Packer Relationships, 8 Drake J. Agric. L. 91 (2003);
Michael Kades, ``Protecting livestock producers and chicken
growers,'' Washington Center for Equitable Growth (May 2022),
https://equitablegrowth.org/wp-content/uploads/2022/05/050522-packers-stockyards-report.pdf (``Section 202's prohibitions on
unjust discrimination and undue preference are not limited to
conduct that destroys or limits competition or creates a monopoly.
These provisions address conduct that impedes a well-functioning
market and deprives livestock and poultry producers of the true
value of their animals. Taken together, these provisions seek to
prevent market abuses.'').
\40\ See Bowman v. U.S. Dep't of Agric., 363 F.2d 81 at 85 (5th
Cir. 1966).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
B. Previous Rulemakings
At the direction of Congress, through the Food, Conservation, and
Energy Act of 2008 (2008 Farm Bill) (Pub. L. 110-246), USDA's then
Grain Inspection, Packers, and Stockyards Administration (GIPSA), which
administered the Packers and Stockyards Act, published a proposed rule
(75 FR 35338; June 22, 2010) (2010 Proposed Rule).\41\ The 2010
Proposed Rule, among other things, banned retaliation as an ``unfair,
unjustly discriminatory, and deceptive practice,'' and clarified when
certain conduct in the livestock and poultry industries represents the
making or giving of an undue or unreasonable preference or advantage or
subjects a person or locality to an undue or unreasonable prejudice or
disadvantage. Congress then prohibited finalization of portions of the
2010 Proposed Rule through appropriations acts for fiscal years 2012
through 2015.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\41\ In 2017, GIPSA merged with the Agricultural Marketing
Service (AMS). AMS now administers the regulations under the Act and
undertook this rulemaking to meet the statutory requirement.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
In 2015, after increased public awareness of issues that the 2010
Proposed Rule attempted to address,\42\ Congress ceased including the
prohibition in appropriations bills, and GIPSA undertook another
rulemaking to address these issues. In 2016, the agency published
another proposed rule (81 FR 92703; December 20, 2016) (2016 Proposed
Rule) attempting to establish what constituted unfair practices and
undue preferences, along with a related interim final rule (81 FR
92566) (2016 IFR). Following the change of administration, the agency
decided to take no further action on the rule. In a notification of no
further action published in the Federal Register (82 FR 48603; October
18, 2017) (2017 No Further Action Notification), GIPSA acknowledged
that some producers, growers, and farm trade groups generally supported
the proposed rule, and many commenters had raised concerns about
growing power imbalances, discrimination, and retaliation. GIPSA,
however, decided not to finalize the 2016 Proposed Rule, in part on the
grounds that it raised the stakes for regulated entities in ways that
could suppress innovation, and contained ambiguous terms that were
likely to increase and prolong litigation between producers and
regulated entities and between regulated entities and AMS. The 2016
Proposed Rule listed six non-exclusive criteria for the Secretary to
consider when determining whether conduct constituted an unfair
practice or preference. In contrast, the current proposed rule focuses
on discrimination, deception, and retaliation.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\42\ ``Chickens: Last Week Tonight with John Oliver,'' HBO, May
17, 2015, available at https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=X9wHzt6gBgI;
see also Nathaniel Haas, ``John Oliver v. chicken,'' Politico, June
1, 2015, available at https://www.politico.com/story/2015/06/john-oliver-vs-chicken-118510.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
In 2020, AMS issued a proposed rule (85 FR 1771; January. 13, 2020)
(2020 Proposed Rule), which was finalized later that year (85 FR 79779;
December. 11, 2020) (2020 Final Rule), which that set out several
(nonexclusive) criteria the Secretary would consider concerning undue
or unreasonable preferences or advantages: whether the preference or
advantage cannot be justified on the basis of a cost savings related to
dealing with different producers, sellers, or growers; cannot be
justified on the basis of meeting a
[[Page 60015]]
competitor's prices; cannot be justified on the basis of meeting other
terms offered by a competitor; and cannot be justified as a reasonable
business decision. In response to the 2020 Proposed Rule, AMS received
numerous comments raising concerns regarding discriminatory and
retaliatory practices; however, AMS stated that the 2020 Final Rule was
intended for the narrower purpose of establishing criteria to
consider.\43\ Specifically, the 2020 Proposed Rule's preamble noted
that discrimination on the basis of race, gender, and other such
protected bases was unlawful and would be addressed as potential
violations of the Act's prohibition against undue prejudices. In August
2021, AMS reiterated this policy in a series of Frequently Asked
Questions (FAQs).\44\ AMS's FAQs also underscored that the rule's
criteria were ``not exhaustive and not determinative.''
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\43\ Undue and Unreasonable Preferences and Advantages Under the
Packers and Stockyards Act, 85 FR 79779 (January 11, 2021), 9 CFR
part 201. Comments available at https://www.regulations.gov/document/AMS-FTPP-18-0101-0001/comment.
\44\ 85 FR 79779; U.S. Department of Agriculture, Agricultural
Marketing Service, ``Frequently Asked Questions on the Enforcement
of Undue and Unreasonable Preferences under the Packers and
Stockyards Act,'' August 2021, available at https://www.ams.usda.gov/rules-regulations/packers-and-stockyards-act/faq
(last accessed June 2022).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
In the context of each of these rulemakings spanning the last
decade, GIPSA, and later AMS, received comments regarding the power
imbalances in the livestock and poultry industries and highlighting the
need for regulations that adequately protect farmers against recurrent
retaliation, deception, and discrimination. Given the consistency of
these assertions, as well as the concerns further brought to light
during the COVID-19 pandemic regarding today's increasingly
concentrated livestock and poultry markets,\45\ AMS believes this
proposed rule is needed to effectuate its responsibility to protect
producers against unlawful practices that exclude, disadvantage,
discriminate against, retaliate against, or deceive them, and that the
rulemaking would promote markets with integrity that are competitive
and inclusive to all.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\45\ U.S. Department of Agriculture, ``Agri-Food Supply Chain
Assessment: Program and Policy Options for Strengthening
Resilience,'' 12-17, February 2021, available at https://www.ams.usda.gov/supply-chain (last accessed Aug. 2022); see also
Agricultural Marketing Service, U.S. Department of Agriculture,
``Agricultural Competition: A Plan in Support of Fair and
Competitive Markets,'' May 2022, available at https://www.ams.usda.gov/reports/agricultural-competition-plan-support-fair-and-competitive-markets (last accessed Aug. 2022).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
II. Undue Prejudices or Disadvantages and Unjust Discriminatory
Practices
A. Agency Interpretation of Undue or Unreasonable Prejudice or
Disadvantage and Unjust Discriminatory Practices
This proposed rule addresses concerns related to undue prejudices
or disadvantages and unjust discrimination. First, proposed Sec.
201.304(a) would establish clearer duties on packers, swine
contractors, and live poultry dealers to ensure full and non-
discriminatory market access for market vulnerable individuals. This
section would also prohibit undue prejudices and disadvantages against
cooperatives.
Second, proposed Sec. 201.304(b) would address retaliation by
setting out protected activities that a covered producer may engage in
but that a regulated entity may not use as grounds for unjust
discrimination or undue prejudice or disadvantage. The proposed
regulations would prohibit regulated entities from retaliating against
a covered producer for participating in a protected activity by
terminating a contract, refusing to renew a contract, offering more
unfavorable contract terms than those generally or ordinarily offered,
refusing to deal, interfering with third-party contracts, and other
actions with a an adverse impact to covered producers. These acts of
retaliation would be unjustly discriminatory and unduly prejudicial and
disadvantageous.
Section 202(b) of the P&S Act (7 U.S.C. 192(b)) prohibits regulated
entities from ``subjecting any particular person or locality to any
undue or unreasonable prejudice or disadvantage in any respect[.]''
Though not defined by the Act, in 1921, legal definitions of prejudice
included anything that ``places the person affected in a more
unfavorable or disadvantageous position than he would otherwise have
occupied.'' \46\ Merriam-Webster.com defines prejudice to include
``injury or damage resulting from some judgment or action of another in
disregard of one's rights'' and ``an irrational attitude of hostility
directed against an individual, a group, a race, or their supposed
characteristics.'' \47\ USDA's Judicial Officer has defined prejudice
in an administrative adjudication as ``subjecting any person to any
injury or damage and not subjecting all similarly situated persons to
the same injury or damage [.]'' \48\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\46\ Roberto v. Catino, 140 Md. 38, 116 A. 873, 875 (1922).
\47\ Merriam-Webster online dictionary, https://www.merriam-webster.com/dictionary/prejudice (accessed June 15, 2022).
\48\ In Re: IBP, Inc., 57 Agric. Dec. 1353 (U.S. Department of
Agriculture July 31, 1998).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Likewise, sec. 202(a) of the P&S Act (7 U.S.C. 192(a)) prohibits
``unjust discrimination.'' but does not expressly define the term.
Merriam-Webster.com defines ``unjust'' as: ``characterized by
injustice: unfair.'' \49\ The common meaning of the word
``discrimination'' means ``differential treatment; especially a failure
to treat all persons equally where no reasonable distinction can be
found between those favored and those not favored.'' \50\ While the
meaning of the word ``discriminatory'' varies depending on the context,
the common definition includes ``applying or favoring discrimination in
treatment.'' \51\ Therefore, under sec. 202(a) of the Act, a regulated
entity treating similar entities differently with respect to livestock,
meats, meat food products, livestock products in unmanufactured form,
or live poultry based on certain conditions is an unjustly
discriminatory practice.\52\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\49\ Merriam-Webster online dictionary, https://www.merriam-webster.com/dictionary/unjust (accessed June 15, 2022).
\50\ Black's Law Dictionary, p. 586 (11th ed. 2019).
\51\ Merriam-Webster online dictionary, https://www.merriam-webster.com/dictionary/discriminatory (accessed June 15, 2022).
\52\ See, also In Re: IBP, Inc., 57 Agric. Dec. 1353 (1998),
rev'd on other grounds by Excel Corp. v. United States Dep't of
Agri., 397 F.3d 1285 (10th Cir. 2005).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The terms ``unjust discrimination'' and ``undue or unreasonable
prejudice or disadvantage'' in the P&S Act do not follow the precise
language of any law that preceded it. This is not without reason. The
P&S Act ``would never have been adopted by the Congress if the
marketing of livestock and the distribution of meat products did not
present problems [that] were insufficiently met by the [then existing]
antitrust laws[.]'' \53\ There were two laws, however, that preceded
the passage of the P&S Act that influenced the inclusions of ``unjust
discrimination'' and ``undue or unreasonable prejudice or
disadvantage'' in the P&S Act: the Clayton Act, and the Interstate
Commerce Act. While both the Clayton Act and the Interstate Commerce
Act informed the P&S Act's prohibition on unfair and discriminatory
practices, the P&S Act has a broader application.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\53\ Crosse & Blackwell Co. v. F.T.C., 262 F.2d 600, 604 (4th
Cir. 1959).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The Clayton Act, passed in 1914, used the language of
discrimination specifically with respect to discriminatory pricing,
prohibiting anyone from ``either directly or
[[Page 60016]]
indirectly [discriminating] in price between different purchasers of
commodities . . . where the effect of such discrimination may be to
substantially lessen competition or create a monopoly in any line of
commerce.'' \54\ The Clayton Act was careful to expressly prohibit
discriminatory pricing in particular. In contrast, the P&S Act does not
include this textual limitation. In addition, the Clayton Act requires
that the discrimination ``may be to substantially effect competition or
create a monopoly.'' The P&S Act, again, is broader:
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\54\ The Clayton Act, sec. 2, Public Law No. 63-212, 38 Stat.
730 (1914).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
[T]he prohibitions of [the Act] go further than the prohibitions in
the Clayton Act. For instance, one of the sections of the Clayton Act
prohibits discrimination in prices as between localities, and then
contains a sort of nullification clause, to the effect that it shall
not prevent anybody from choosing his own customers or making
discriminations in prices where there is a difference in quality or a
difference in transportation charges, and so forth, while this bill
makes any undue or unreasonable discrimination as between localities or
between persons unlawful.\55\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\55\ 61 Cong. Rec. 1888 (1921) (statement of Rep. Anderson).
Likewise, the Interstate Commerce Act was an important template for
the P&S Act. The P&S Act's statutory history is replete with references
and comparisons, in general terms, to the Interstate Commerce Act.
Passed in 1887, the Interstate Commerce Act forbade common carriers--
primarily meaning railroads--from undue preferences, prejudices, and
discrimination in their rates and charges between connecting lines.\56\
As the Supreme Court explained the Interstate Commerce Act in 1934:
``The purpose . . . was to bring into existence a body which, from its
special character, would be best fitted to determine, among other
things, whether upon the facts in a given case there is an unjust
discrimination against interstate commerce.'' \57\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\56\ Act of February 4, 1887 (Interstate Commerce Act), sec. 3,
Public Law 49-41, February 4, 1887; Enrolled Acts and Resolutions of
Congress, 1789; General Records of the United States Government,
1778--1992; Record Group 11; National Archives.
\57\ State of Fla. v. United States, 292 U.S. 1, 12, 54 S. Ct.
603, 608, 78 L. Ed. 1077 (1934) (citing United States v. Louisville
& Nashville R.R. Co., 235 U.S. 314, 320 (1914)).''[F]rom the
beginning the very purpose for which the Commission was created was
to . . . decide whether from facts, disputed or undisputed [whether
a] preference or discrimination existed.'' Louisville and Nashville
R.R. Co., 235 U.S. at 320.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
With respect to the courts' interpretation of unjustly
discriminatory practices under the P&S Act, there are few Federal cases
that explore the difference between unjust discrimination and the other
provisions of the Act. Because of the P&S Act's similarity to the
Clayton Act, the Seventh Circuit holds that unjust discrimination has
included below-cost sales which injure sellers or primary line
competition, even if the buyers or secondary-line competition are not
affected. See Wilson & Co. v. Benson, 286 F.2d 891, 895 (7th Cir.
1961). Likewise, that circuit holds that price discrimination in favor
of a larger grocery store chain, and higher prices to its competitors,
are another type of unjust discrimination that the Act has prevented.
Swift & Co. v. United States, 317 F.2d 53, 55-56 (7th Cir. 1963).
Moreover, the Supreme Court has held that when discrimination is used
as an attempt to limit competition, it is a monopoly practice. See
Denver Union Stock Yard Co. v. Producers Livestock Mktg., 356 U.S. 282,
289 (1958) (interpreting sec. 312 of the Act and finding that
regulations aimed at preventing market agencies registered at one
stockyard from doing business for producers at any other market within
a normal marketing area to be a monopoly practice).
AMS proposes this regulation to protect the integrity of the market
as a competitive, price-clearing, economically open commercial endeavor
by eliminating or restraining prejudicial discrimination. This includes
prejudicial discriminatory behaviors such as those that adversely
impact open access by competitors and market participants (through
certain exclusionary prejudices, such as denying or disadvantaging an
individual's access to market on grounds which could include race,
gender, religion, or other bases; or retaliatory discrimination for
engaging in certain basic protected activities closely tied to the
basic requirements of being in the business of livestock, poultry, and
related markets covered under the Act), and otherwise exert forms of
control or dependency that limit the economic freedom of those
participating in the market.\58\ The harms these proposed regulations
aim to prevent are the kinds of discrimination (and, as discussed
below, deceptive) practices that dominant firms can use to limit
competition and interfere with the operation of the market, including
across the entire supply chain with respect to livestock, meats, meat
food products, livestock products in unmanufactured form, or for any
live poultry dealer with respect to live poultry.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\58\ Michael Kades, ``Protecting Livestock Producers and Chicken
Growers,'' Washington Center for Equitable Growth (May 5, 2022),
available at https://equitablegrowth.org/research-paper/protecting-livestock-producers-and-chicken-growers/.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
B. Prohibited Undue Prejudices or Disadvantages and Unjust
Discrimination--Proposed Sec. 201.304(a)(1)
Section 201.301 of the proposed regulations would protect the
integrity of the market, promoting fairness and competition by
prohibiting undue prejudices and disadvantages and unjust
discrimination that inhibit inclusive market access and treatment.
Specifically, proposed Sec. 201.304(a)(1) would prohibit prejudice,
disadvantage, or the denial or reduction of market access by regulated
entities against covered producers based on their status, as defined in
the regulation, of being ``market vulnerable'' producers. This term is
defined as membership in a group that has been subjected to, or is at
heightened risk of, adversely differential treatment in the
marketplace. AMS seeks comments on whether specific groups should be
named in the definition of a market vulnerable individual as examples
of market vulnerable individuals and, if so, requests supporting
evidence on the historical treatment of such groups. AMS also seeks
comment on whether, alternatively, prohibitions on undue prejudice or
disadvantage or unjust discrimination would best be addressed by
identifying defined protected classes, and if so, which protected
classes. The intent of the proposed regulation is to help break down
barriers that may serve to exclude or disadvantage certain covered
producers, while leaving room for differential treatment based on
legitimate business purposes.
This proposal defines a covered producer as a livestock producer
(as defined in the regulation at proposed Sec. 201.302) or swine
production contract grower or poultry grower as defined in sec. 2(a) of
the Act. While swine contract producers and poultry growers are defined
in the Act, AMS believes the Act is properly read to protect livestock
producers from unjustly prejudicial and discriminatory practices. To
effectuate this purpose, this proposed rule defines livestock producer
as any person engaged in the raising and caring for livestock by the
producer or another person, whether the livestock is owned by the
producer or by another person, but not an employee of the owner of the
livestock. This definition is designed to
[[Page 60017]]
capture the vast majority of market participants who are dependent on
regulated entities to engage in the livestock business. AMS seeks
comment on whether to limit the definition to persons engaging in the
raising and caring for livestock in the chain of slaughter, or whether
such limitation is unnecessary or improperly limits the coverage of the
Act.
The principal purpose of this proposed approach is to address
prejudices in the marketplace against producers that are more
vulnerable to such treatment and to stop unjust discrimination. AMS
views vulnerability to adverse marketplace treatment to include, but
not be limited to, exclusion or disadvantage on the basis of race,
ethnicity, or sex or gender prejudices (including discrimination
against an individual for being lesbian, gay, transgender, or queer),
religion, disability, or age.\59\ AMS seeks comment on these bases, and
whether there are other bases for vulnerability to adverse marketplace
treatment.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\59\ Supreme Court case law has established that discriminating
against an individual for being lesbian, gay, transgender or queer
is discrimination on the basis of sex or gender prejudices. Bostock
v. Clayton Cnty., Georgia, 140 S. Ct. 1731, 1741 (2020) (``[I]t is
impossible to discriminate against a person for being homosexual or
transgender without discriminating against that individual based on
sex.'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
This proposed rule aims to ensure more inclusive market competition
and address allegations related to undue prejudices through enforceable
regulatory prohibitions. The proposed prohibitions would protect
producers at both individual and market-wide levels from undue
prejudices and disadvantages and unjust discrimination--both of which
AMS has determined violate the P&S Act. The Secretary is empowered
under the P&S Act to address harms in their incipiency.\60\ Moreover,
given its experience interacting with producers and regulated entities,
AMS believes that individual instances of prejudice and discrimination
can have a cumulative adverse effect on relevant markets, including the
national market.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\60\ E.g. Bowman v. United States Dep't of Agric., 363 F.2d 81,
85 (5th Cir. 1966) (```the Act is designed to `* * * prevent
potential injury by stopping unlawful practices in their incipiency.
Proof of a particular injury is not required.' '').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
AMS believes the proposed regulatory scheme results in a flexible
approach to resolving marketplace vulnerabilities. AMS's proposed
regulatory approach of prohibiting unjust discrimination and undue
prejudices and disadvantages against market vulnerable producers
recognizes that discrimination against producers may evolve. AMS
expects the proposed definition will be sufficiently responsive to the
particular facts of given cases and particular markets over time. AMS
is considering issuing guidance on the proposed regulatory approach.
AMS is seeking comment on the definition of ``market vulnerable
producers.'' AMS's goal is to appropriately govern regulated entities'
conduct for the purpose of ensuring inclusive competition in the
marketplace, grounded in the Act's authorities. This includes seeking
comment on whether it should delineate specific categories of
vulnerable producers on the basis of membership in groups that have
historically been subject to adverse treatment owing to racial, ethnic,
gender, or religious prejudices. If so, AMS solicits supporting
evidence regarding the historical adverse treatment of such groups.
AMS also seeks comment on the use of a ``market vulnerable
producer'' approach--rather than a list of protected classes that may
not be discriminated against--to the regulatory prohibition against
discrimination. In the alternative to using the market vulnerable
producer approach, the agency is considering whether this regulation
should ban discrimination against specific classes, such as on the
basis of race, color, national origin, religion, sex, sexual
orientation, gender identity, age, disability, marital status, or
family status. Such an approach would differ from the market vulnerable
individual approach and would instead more closely follow the civil
rights laws that prohibit prejudicial discrimination against certain
protected classes.
The prohibition on prejudice against cooperatives also seeks to
prevent barriers to market access for cooperatives. Congress has long
recognized the need to provide enhanced protections for cooperatives,
as embodied for example in the Agricultural Fair Practices Act of 1967
(Pub. L. 90-288), which protects producers' rights to form a
cooperative.\61\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\61\ For the purposes of this preamble, a cooperative is an
incorporated or unincorporated association of producers, with or
without capital stock, formed for mutual benefit of its members.
Farm cooperatives are formed under state, not Federal law, even
though cooperatives have Federal protections. See James B. Dean &
Thomas Earl Geu, The Uniform Limited Cooperative Association Act: An
Introduction, 13 Drake J. Agric. L. 63, 67 (2008) (``There is,
however, no single type of cooperative. Although much of the law
that has developed around cooperatives has developed with respect to
agricultural cooperatives, cooperatives exist in many areas . . .
including housing, insurance, banking, health care, and retail
sales, among others.''). Cooperatives can both be buyers and sellers
of agricultural products. Cooperatives made up of sellers, because
they jointly fix the prices of their goods, are legally permitted to
market the products they produce when the cooperative organization
meets the requirements of the Capper-Volstead Act (see 7 U.S.C. 291)
or the Clayton Act (see 15 U.S.C. 17).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
i. Authority Provided by the Act
There is no indication that Congress intended to exempt any
practice of regulated entities affecting producers covered under the
Act.\62\ The P&S Act, through secs. 202(a) and (b), broadly prohibits
certain practices or devices, including undue or unreasonable
prejudices and disadvantages and unjust discrimination. Sections 202(a)
and (b) of the Act identify a number of prohibited actions with respect
to livestock, meats, meat food products, or livestock products in
unmanufactured form, or for any live poultry dealer with respect to
live poultry. To effectuate these statutory prohibitions, AMS proposes
to prohibit specific undue and unreasonable prejudices, disadvantages,
and discrimination against any covered producer. AMS also seeks comment
on whether to extend these protections to all persons buying or selling
meat and meat food products in markets under the jurisdiction of the
Act.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\62\ See 7 U.S.C. 193. C.f. Mitchell v. United States, 313 U.S.
80, 94, 61 S. Ct. 873, 877, 85 L. Ed. 1201 (1941) (``We have
repeatedly said that it is apparent from the legislative history of
the Act that not only was the evil of discrimination the principal
thing aimed at, but that there is no basis for the contention that
Congress intended to exempt any discriminatory action or practice of
interstate carriers affecting interstate commerce which it had
authority to reach.'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
In enacting the P&S Act, Congress cast a wide net to capture all
acts of unjust discrimination and unreasonable prejudice against any
particular person. The Act's prohibition of anti-competitive,
discriminatory, and unreasonably prejudicial actions against a
particular person was not a new statutory concept, as the Interstate
Commerce Act also banned unreasonable prejudices and discriminatory
practices well before the enactment of the P&S Act. While a finding of
being within the Interstate Commerce Act's (ICA) scope is not a
necessary precondition for a violation of the P&S Act, the comparison
is nevertheless useful, especially with respect to the structure and
design of provisions governing undue prejudices. A comparison is
provided in Table 1, below.
In Mitchell v. U.S., the Supreme Court decided that the Interstate
Commerce Act prohibited discrimination based on race. 313 U.S. 80
(1941). The Supreme Court held that ``it is apparent from the
legislative history of the Interstate
[[Page 60018]]
Commerce Act that not only was the evil of discrimination the principal
thing aimed at, but that there is no basis for the contention that
Congress intended to exempt any discriminatory action or practice of
interstate carriers affecting interstate commerce which it had
authority to reach.'' \63\ Further, the Court isolated a section of the
Interstate Commerce Act and noted that, ``Paragraph 1 of Section 3 of
the Act says explicitly that it shall be unlawful for any common
carrier subject to the Act `to subject any particular person * * * to
any undue or unreasonable prejudice or disadvantage in any respect
whatsoever.'' \64\ (Emphasis added) The Court found that unreasonable
prejudice against an individual based on race was a violation and
concluded that, ``the Interstate Commerce Act expressly extends its
prohibitions to the subjecting of `any particular person' to
unreasonable discriminations.'' \65\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\63\ Id. at 94.
\64\ Id. at 95.
\65\ Id. at 97.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The P&S Act contains similar but broader language than the
Interstate Commerce Act sec. 3 in sec. 202, which reads, ``It shall be
unlawful for any packer or swine contractor with respect to livestock,
meats, meat food products, or livestock products in unmanufactured
form, or for any live poultry dealer with respect to live poultry, to:
(a) Engage in or use any unfair, unjustly discriminatory, or deceptive
practice or device; or (b) Make or give any undue or unreasonable
preference or advantage to any particular person or locality in any
respect, or subject any particular person or locality to any undue or
unreasonable prejudice or disadvantage in any respect. . .'' (emphasis
added). Table 1 illustrates where the text between the two Acts is
similar, and also how the Packers and Stockyards Act is broader.\66\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\66\ For more on the relationship between the Interstate
Commerce Act and the P&S Act in this area, see Michael Kades,
``Protecting Livestock Producers and Chicken Growers,'' Washington
Center for Equitable Growth, at 66 (May 2022) discussing Wheeler v.
Pilgrim's Pride Corp., 591 F.3d 355, 368-369 (5th Cir 2009) (en
banc) (J. Jones concurring): ``In all the cases discussed by the
concurrence dealing with both terms [under the ICA], the defendant
faced charges that it treated customers differently. According to
the court, `railway companies are only bound to give the same terms
to all persons alike under the same conditions.' If the conditions
are different, then different treatment is merited. Further,
`competition between rival routes is one of the matters which may
lawfully be considered in making rates.' Differential treatment
driven by competitive forces is not a violation. Acknowledging that
competition can justify differential treatment of customers is
different than requiring the plaintiff to prove anticompetitive harm
to establish a violation.''
Table 1--Comparison of the Interstate Commerce Act and the Packers &
Stockyards Act
------------------------------------------------------------------------
P&S Act, Section 202 [7
Interstate Commerce Act (1887 text) U.S.C.192]. Unlawful practices
Sec. 3. enumerated
------------------------------------------------------------------------
That it shall be unlawful for any It shall be unlawful for any
common carrier subject to the packer or swine contractor
provisions of this act to make or give with respect to livestock,
any undue or unreasonable preference meats, meat food products, or
or advantage to any particular person, livestock products in
company, firm, corporation, or unmanufactured form, or for
locality, or any particular any live poultry dealer with
description of traffic, in any respect respect to live poultry, to:
whatsoever, (a) Engage in or use any
or to subject any particular person, unfair, unjustly
company, firm, corporation, or discriminatory, or deceptive
locality, or any particular practice or device; or
description of traffic, to any undue (b) Make or give any undue or
or unreasonable prejudice or unreasonable preference or
disadvantage in any respect advantage to any particular
whatsoever. person or locality in any
Every common carrier subject to the respect, or subject any
provisions of this act . . . shall not particular person or locality
discriminate in their rates and to any undue or unreasonable
charges between such connecting prejudice or disadvantage in
lines[.] (emphasis added). any respect; (emphasis added).
------------------------------------------------------------------------
As shown in Table 1, unlike the Interstate Commerce Act, the P&S
Act in secs. 202(a) and (b) prohibits undue or unreasonable prejudices
or disadvantages as well as deception and unjust discrimination
(without limitation to discrimination in rates and charges in
particular). In this proposed rulemaking, AMS incorporates the language
from sec. 202 to prohibit acts of unreasonable prejudice and to prevent
unreasonable discrimination including but not limited to the race
discrimination that the Court found to be violative of the Interstate
Commerce Act in Mitchell.
This proposed regulation sets forth specific prohibitions on
prejudicial or discriminatory acts or practices against individuals
that are sufficient to demonstrate violation of the P&S Act without the
need to further establish broad-based, market-wide prejudicial or
discriminatory outcomes or harms. The prohibitions on regulated
entities adversely treating individual producers set forth in this
proposed rule address the types of harms the P&S Act is intended to
prevent. AMS believes that preventing broad-based exclusion is most
effectively enforced at the individual producer level when the conduct
is in its incipiency.\67\ To further allow for effective enforcement of
the statute, AMS is also proposing a recordkeeping requirement to
support evaluation of regulated entity compliance.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\67\ ``[T]he purpose of the Act is to halt unfair trade
practices in their incipiency, before harm has been suffered.'' See
Farrow v. U.S. Dep't of Agr., 760 F.2d 211, 215 (8th Cir. 1985)
(citing De Jong Packing Co. v. U.S. Dep't of Agric., 618 F.2d 1329,
1336-37 (9th Cir. 1980)); Swift & Co. v. United States, 393 F.2d
247, 252 (7th Cir. 1968); Armour and Company v. United States, 402
F.2d 712, 723 n. 12 (7th Cir.1968).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
ii. Economic Rationale
Marketplace integrity and market access were leading policy goals
at the time of the Act's passage. ``The primary purpose of [the P&S
Act] is to assure fair competition and fair-trade practices in
livestock marketing and in the meatpacking industry . . . The Act
provides that meatpackers subject to its provisions shall not engage in
practices that restrain commerce or create a monopoly. They are also
prohibited from engaging in any . . . unjust discriminatory practice or
device. . .'' (emphasis added). AMS believes that discrimination in the
form of prejudice or retaliation against a covered producer on the
basis of certain non-economic prejudices restrains commerce, including
competition, and effects undue and unjust trade practices by denying or
inhibiting full market access for producers. These limitations on
market access are contrary to the primary purposes of the Act--assuring
fair trade practices and competitive markets that producers can access,
as well as prohibiting unjust discrimination. For these reasons, AMS
has determined that prejudice on certain non-economic bases, as set
forth under ``market vulnerable individual,'' is undue and unjust.
[[Page 60019]]
Undue prejudice is, furthermore, a market abuse that undermines
market integrity, deprives the producer of the benefit of the market,
and prevents the producer from obtaining the true market value of the
livestock, or their services.\68\ While such a pathway for harm is
sufficient justification for the rulemaking, prejudicial discrimination
is also anti-competitive and leads to economic inefficiencies. This
section addresses the economics of these issues, including by
describing the history of prejudice and discrimination and their
economic consequences in the agricultural sector and other economic
sectors for market vulnerable individuals and groups.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\68\ See Stafford v. Wallace, 258 U.S. 495 (1922).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Background and History of Economic Impacts of Prejudice and Unjust
Discrimination in Agricultural and Other Economic Sectors
While not necessarily tied exclusively to the operation of
livestock markets, it is well-documented that undue prejudice has
occurred and persists in agricultural markets and has led to market
abuse. For example, in the earlier part of the 1900s agricultural
landholders conspired to restrict land sales and the administration of
Federal farm support programs to Black people, including those engaged
in livestock production.\69\ A 1959 paper reported ``significant market
discrimination'' against Black American producers in the Southern
United States.\70\ The loss of heirs' property--land that is passed
down from generation to generation without a will or other legal
documentation--has been the leading cause of Black land loss in US
agriculture.\71\ Some of the loss of heirs' property was the direct
result of predatory and discriminatory abuse of partition sales
processes and inequities in access and use of legal and other estate
planning tools among Black populations.\72\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\69\ Francis, Dania V., Darrick Hamilton, Thomas W. Mitchell,
Nathan A. Rosenberg, and Bryce Wilson Stucki. ``Black Land Loss:
1920-1997.'' In AEA Papers and Proceedings, vol. 112, pp. 38-42.
American Economic Association, 2022.
\70\ Tang, Anthony M. ``Economic development and changing
consequences of race discrimination in Southern agriculture.''
Journal of Farm Economics 41, no. 5 (1959): 1113-1126.
\71\ U.S. Department of Agriculture, National Agricultural
Library, ``Heirs' Property,'' https://www.nal.usda.gov/farms-and-agricultural-production-systems/heirs-property (last accessed Aug.
2022).
\72\ Mitchell, Thomas W. 2019. Historic Partition Law Reform: A
Game Changer for Heirs' Property Owners. In Heirs' property and land
fractionation: fostering stable ownership to prevent land loss and
abandonment. https://www.fs.usda.gov/treesearch/pubs/58543 (last
accessed 8/9/2022).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The Federal Government also played a role in discriminatory
practices, which had significant economic consequences for Black
producers especially. Reports from the U.S. Commission on Civil Rights
in 1965 and 1982 documented discrimination in the provision of USDA
programs and other prejudicial factors leading to the decline in Black
farming.\73\ In the late 1990s, Black producers won a lawsuit filed
against USDA for engaging in discriminatory practices in its farm loan
programs--practices which led to financial ruin and land loss for many
Black farmers.\74\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\73\ U.S. Commission on Civil Rights. 1965. Equal Opportunity in
Farm Programs: An Appraisal of Services Rendered by Agencies of the
U.S. Department of Agriculture. https://files.eric.ed.gov/fulltext/ED068206.pdfUS Commission on Civil Rights. 1982. ``The Decline of
Black Farming in America.'' https://eric.ed.gov/?id=ED222604.
\74\ Feder, J. and T. Cowan. 2013. ``Garcia v. Vilsack: A Policy
and Legal Analysis of a USDA Discrimination Case'', Congressional
Research Service report number 7-5700, February 22, 2013.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
These, and other widespread discriminatory practices, help explain
the relative greater decrease in the number of Black producers over the
course of the twentieth century.\75\ Indeed, White farm ownership
declined 62 percent and Black farm ownership 96 percent between 1930
and 2012.\76\ Over the same period, total acres operated by Whites
declined 9 percent and Blacks by 90 percent.\77\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\75\ Touzeau, Leslie. 2019. ``Being Stewards of Land Is Our
Legacy': Exploring the Lived Experiences of Young Black Farmers.''
Journal of Agriculture, Food Systems, and Community Development 8
(4): 1-6. https://doi.org/10.5304/jafscd.2019.084.007.
\76\ Francis, Dania V., Darrick Hamilton, Thomas W. Mitchell,
Nathan A. Rosenberg, and Bryce Wilson Stucki. ``Black Land Loss:
1920-1997.'' In AEA Papers and Proceedings, vol. 112, pp. 38-42.
American Economic Association, 2022; Wood, S., & Gilbert, J. (2000,
Spring). Returning African-American farmers to the land: Recent
trends and a policy rationale. The Review of Black Political
Economy, 27, 43-64. Available at https://doi.org/10.1007/BF02717262.
Touzeau, Leslie. 2019. ```Being Stewards of Land Is Our Legacy':
Exploring the Lived Experiences of Young Black Farmers.'' Journal of
Agriculture, Food Systems, and Community Development 8 (4): 1-6.
https://doi.org/10.5304/jafscd.2019.084.007.
\77\ The Agricultural Census figures on farm operations for 2012
are downloaded from the National Agricultural Statistics Service's
Quick Stats and figures from 1930 are from volume 4 of the 1930
Census, https://agcensus.library.cornell.edu/census_year/1930-census/.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Other racial and ethnic minorities have also been negatively
impacted by prejudicial acts. Latino and Indigenous people farming on
reservations lost their farmland through the same abuses of partition
sale processes as Black farmers. Between 1900 and 2017, the percent of
all producers identifying as White increased nine percentages points to
96 percent, while American Indian or Alaska Native producers increased
by only 1.3 percentage points, to 2.3 percent.\78\ Hispanic or Latino
farmers increased by only 2.4 percentage points between 1920 and 2017,
to 3.4 percent. Racial and ethnic inequities in farmland ownership and
indicators of farm-related wealth have also been observed in recent
years.\79\ Concerns have also been highlighted regarding the treatment
of Asian American and Pacific Islander poultry growers, in particular
that immigrant communities may not appreciate the risks of contractual
arrangements due to language barriers.\80\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\78\ Casey, Alyssa R. Racial Equity in U.S. Farming: Background
in Brief 2021. Congressional Research Service. https://crsreports.congress.gov/product/pdf/R/R46969.
\79\ Horst, M., Marion, A. ``Racial, ethnic and gender
inequities in farmland ownership and farming in the U.S.'' Agric Hum
Values 36, 1-16 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10460-018-9883-3.
\80\ Christopher Leonard, ``The Meat Racket,'' (2015) and Witt,
Howard. ``Hmong poultry farmers cry foul, sue'' Chicago Tribune. May
15, 2006. Available online at: https://www.chicagotribune.com/news/ct-xpm-2006-05-15-0605150155-story.html.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Complete foreclosure of market access, for example through the loss
of land or other capital, has clear adverse economic outcomes for
protected groups who wish to engage in the agricultural sector but
cannot. At the same time, discriminatory acts reduce economic
opportunity for individuals in protected groups who are able to
maintain market access. This not only causes economic harm to these
groups but also has broader impacts.
Studies documenting these economic impacts of prejudicial
discrimination in the agricultural sector are relatively sparse, partly
due to data limitations. However, economic studies focused on
employment practices, financial transactions, housing, and other
markets outside the agricultural sector demonstrate how discrimination
may cause economic harm across all types of markets, including
agricultural ones. As early as the 1950s, economic studies documented
racial wage gaps between
[[Page 60020]]
workers.\81\ Enabled by a lack of competition among employers, this
discrimination not only had adverse economic impacts for protected
groups but also for employers who, due to their own discriminatory
actions, ultimately paid higher wages for some equally productive
workers.\82\ Recent studies highlight how racial wealth disparities
reduce labor market competition, since reduced wealth hinders job
search abilities.\83\ On the flip side, recent research shows that
increased labor market participation among racial minorities and women
contributed to increased economic output during the second half of the
twentieth century.\84\ Research on the U.S. patent system finds that
racially-motivated violent acts reduced the number of patents by Black
inventors in the U.S. during the late 1800s and through the middle of
the twentieth century.\85\ These patents could have led to new wealth
for the inventors and increased business investments, potentially
contributing to overall economic growth. In an analysis of data from
the National Survey of Small Business Finances, Black led-businesses
were found to have been more frequently issued loans with higher
interest rates and other unfavorable terms relative to white or male-
led businesses, which could reduce productivity and innovation in the
broader economy.\86\ In housing, recent evidence shows that minority
households are steered towards areas with higher rates of poverty,
crime, and pollution, and less economic opportunity.\87\ Combined,
these discriminatory practices have large economic consequences. A 2020
study estimates that if racial gaps in wages, housing, access to higher
education, and lending were closed, the U.S. would experience a $5
trillion dollar increase in gross domestic product (GDP) from 2020 to
2025.\88\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\81\ Bayer, P., and K. K. Charles. ``Divergent Paths: A New
Perspective on Earnings Differences Between Black and White Men
since 1940.'' The Quarterly Journal of Economics (2018), 1459-1501.
Becker, G.S. The Economics of Discrimination. First Edition, The
University of Chicago Press, 1957.
\82\ Becker, G.S. The Economics of Discrimination. First
Edition, The University of Chicago Press, 1957.
\83\ Kate Bahn, Mark Stelzner, and Emilie Openchowski, ``Wage
discrimination and the exploitation of workers in the U.S. labor
market,'' Washington Center for Equitable Growth, September 2020,
available at https://equitablegrowth.org/research-paper/wage-discrimination-and-the-exploitation-of-workers-in-the-u-s-labor-market/?longform=true.
\84\ Hsieh et al., ``The Allocation of Talent and U.S. Economic
Growth,'' 2019, available at https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.3982/ECTA11427.
\85\ Cook, Lisa D. ``Violence and economic activity: evidence
from African American patents, 1870-1940.'' Journal of Economic
Growth 19, no. 2 (2014): 221-257.
\86\ Laura Alfaro, Ester Faia, and Camelia Minoiu,
``Distributional Consequences of Monetary Policy Across Races:
Evidence from the U.S. Credit Register'' April 2022, available at
https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=4096092; Ken S.
Cavalluzzo, Linda C. Cavalluzzo, and John D. Wolken, ``Competition,
Small Business Financing, and Discrimination: Evidence from a New
Survey,'' The Journal of Business, October 2022, available at
https://www.jstor.org/stable/pdf/10.1086/341638.pdf?refreqid=excelsior%3Ab05443d9a80629ef03bbe4cb6e7747e4&ab_segments=&origin=&acceptTC=1.
\87\ Christensen, Peter, and Christopher Timmins. ``Sorting or
steering: The effects of housing discrimination on neighborhood
choice.'' Journal of Political Economy 130, no. 8 (2022): 2110-2163.
\88\ Closing the Racial Wealth Gap: The Economic Costs of Black
Inequality in the United States. Citi GPS: Global Perspectives and
Solutions. 2020. Available at https://ir.citi.com/NvIUklHPilz14Hwd3oxqZBLMn1_XPqo5FrxsZD0x6hhil84ZxaxEuJUWmak51UHvYk75VKeHCMI%3D.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Undue Prejudice and Economic Inefficiency
Prejudicial discrimination has been theorized and observed to be an
artificial barrier to market activities, and as such, it can create a
market distortion.\89\ A variety of pathways for agricultural market
distortions due to discrimination are possible. For example, if prices
paid for otherwise identical cattle differed because of the race,
ethnicity, or other producer characteristics that do not have any
bearing on productivity, rather than the on the value of the marginal
product of the cattle, then the prejudice based on these
characteristics distorts prices and in turn both output and investment.
While the specifics of producer returns in contract production are
different from marketed production, producers receiving a lower
contract payment rate or other unfavorable contract terms simply
because of the producers' race or other personal characteristics would
likewise induce market distortions.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\89\ Stiglitz, J. ``Approaches to the Economics of
Discrimination'', American Economic Review, vol. 63/2, May 1973:
287-295.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Prejudicial discrimination can take other forms besides wage,
contract, or price differentials, such as exclusionary practices in
product purchases or sales, or higher lending costs. These examples of
artificial barriers preventing resources from moving to their highest
and best uses via allocative efficiency, such that marginal benefits
equal marginal costs, lead to market inefficiency. Lowering the level
of this market distortion would increase market efficiency, albeit
noting there is limited information to empirically assess the impacts
of discrimination on efficiency in agricultural markets.
Undue Prejudice and Potential Market Abuse in Concentrated Livestock
Markets
Like in other parts of the economy and in other types of markets,
those participating in agricultural markets from groups that have and
continue to suffer racial, ethnic, gender, and religious prejudices may
be particularly vulnerable to market abuses, especially in concentrated
markets such as in the livestock sector. This is because they currently
represent not only a very small share of producers in the industry,
including those in the livestock sector and among producers who have
production contracts, but their size, sales, and incomes are lower than
other producers, leaving them more economically isolated and with fewer
economic resources to counteract concentrated market forces and actors.
In the livestock sector, the results of historical prejudice and
the risk of present-day prejudice are apparent when looking at data
from the 2017 Census of Agriculture, which show that currently a very
small fraction of livestock farms with production contracts are
operated by Black, Asian, American Indian, or Native Hawaiian producers
(Figure 1). As described earlier in this section, discriminatory acts,
especially against Black producers, undoubtedly contributed to the
current low levels of racial and ethnic minority participation in the
livestock sector, including among producers with production contracts.
These remaining producers may be particularly vulnerable to market
abuses in concentrated livestock markets.
[[Page 60021]]
[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP03OC22.069
Disparities in farm size and income across racial and ethnic groups
also exist among livestock and poultry farms with production contracts,
highlighting additional vulnerability for particular groups in the
sector. Figure 2 shows the percentage and number of livestock and
poultry farms with production contracts by the reported race or
ethnicity of their producers, categorized by level of Gross Cash Farm
Income (GCFI), which includes commodity cash receipts, farm-related
income, and Government payments.\90\ USDA's Economic Research Service
(ERS) classifies small farms as having a GCFI less than $150,000 and up
to $349,999 per year, mid-sized farms as having GCFI between $350,000
and $999,999, and large-scale farms as having a GCFI equal to or
greater than $1,000,000. Farms are also classified as being non-family
farms, which are farms in which an operator or persons related to the
operator do not own a majority of the business.\91\ These data indicate
that contracted livestock and poultry farms with producers who identify
as Black and Native Hawaiian are more likely to be in the lower income
GCFI categories than their white counterparts. To a lesser extent,
farms with producers identifying as Native American also tend to be in
the lower income GCFI categories than their White counterparts' farms.
Markets dominated by one or a few large packers or live poultry dealers
may be less accessible to these smaller farms, which have limited
financial or other economic resources with which to engage. They may
also be more vulnerable to discriminatory acts or market abuses such as
retaliation.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\90\ U.S. Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service,
``Most farms are small, but large-scale farms account for almost
half of production,'' available at: https://www.ers.usda.gov/data-products/chart-gallery/gallery/chart-detail/?chartId=58288 (last
accessed Aug, 2022).
\91\ U.S. Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service,
``Farm Structure and Contracting,'' available at: https://www.ers.usda.gov/topics/farm-economy/farm-structure-and-organization/farm-structure-and-contracting/ (last accessed Aug.
2022).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
[[Page 60022]]
[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP03OC22.070
iii. Specific Proposed Bases
In determining the proposed bases for protection under this
section, AMS looked to several sources, including the Statement of
General Policy Under the Packers and Stockyards Act published by the
Secretary of Agriculture in 1968 (Statement of General Policy) (9 CFR
203.12(f)), the regulations governing USDA-conducted programs, and a
series of statutes identifying producers that Congress has determined
face special disadvantages, are underserved, or are otherwise more
vulnerable to prejudices.
The Statement of General Policy reflects the current USDA policy on
the enforcement of the P&S Act. The Statement of General Policy
provides in part that it's a violation of sections 304, 307, and 312(a)
of the Packers and Stockyards Act for a stockyard owner or market
agency to discriminate, in the furnishing of stockyard services or
facilities or in establishing rules or regulations at the stockyard,
because of race, religion, color, or national origin of those persons
using the stockyard services or facilities. Such services and
facilities include, but are not limited to, the restaurant, restrooms,
drinking fountains, lounge accommodations, those furnished for the
selling, weighing, or other handling of the livestock, and facilities
for observing such services.
While this part of the Statement of General Policy applies to
violations of secs. 304, 307, and 312(a) of the Act--related to the
provision of services and facilities at stockyards on an unreasonable
and discriminatory basis, almost identical prohibitive language is used
in sec. 202 of the Act. Section 202 pertains to packers, swine
contractors, and live poultry dealers. Section 202(a) of the Act
prohibits any unjustly discriminatory practice or device with respect
to livestock, meats, meat food products or livestock products in
manufactured form, or live poultry.
AMS also considered USDA's general regulatory prohibition against
discrimination in USDA programs, which governs how USDA provides
services to producers and growers. Most recently updated in 2014, it
offers a more current interpretation of anti-discrimination standards.
The relevant provision provides that no agency, officer, or employee of
the USDA shall, on the grounds of race, color, national origin,
religion, sex, sexual orientation, disability, age, marital status,
family/parental status, income derived from a public assistance
program, political beliefs, or gender identity, exclude from
participation in, deny the benefits of, or subject to discrimination
any person in the United States under any program or activity conducted
by the USDA.\92\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\92\ 7 CFR 15d.3; U.S. Department of Agriculture,
``Nondiscrimination in Programs or Activities Conducted by the
United States Department of Agriculture,'' 79 FR 41406, July 16,
2014, available at https://www.federalregister.gov/documents/2014/07/16/2014-16325/nondiscrimination-in-programs-or-activities-conducted-by-the-united-states-department-of-agriculture (last
accessed 8/9/2022).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
In that rulemaking, USDA identified areas where discrimination
against a producer is an unacceptable denial of access to USDA's
services.
[[Page 60023]]
AMS also looked to the legislative mandates that emerged over the
last thirty years, directing USDA to make extra efforts to overcome the
barriers that prevent members of those groups from accessing USDA's
services and agricultural markets generally.\93\ Congress adopted
numerous statutes seeking to remedy market access barriers on the basis
of prejudices across a wide range of areas, including: 7 U.S.C. 8711
(base acres); 7 U.S.C. 2003 (target participation rates); 7 U.S.C. 7333
(Administration and operation of noninsured crop assistance program); 7
U.S.C. 1932 (Assistance for rural entities); 16 U.S.C. 2202a, 3801,
3835, 3839aa-2, 3841, and 3844 (conservation); 7 U.S.C. 8111 (Biomass
Crop Assistance Program); 7 U.S.C. 1508 (Federal crop insurance,
covering underserved producers defined as new, beginning, and socially
disadvantaged farmers or ranchers and including members of an Indian
tribe); and 16 U.S.C. 3871e(d) (conservation, covering historically
underserved producers defined as beginning, veteran, socially
disadvantaged, and limited-resource farmers and ranchers). In 25 U.S.C.
4301(a) and elsewhere, Congress has clearly expressed its intent for
the United States government to encourage and foster tribal commerce
and economic development.\94\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\93\ For background, see Congressional Research Service,
Defining a Socially Disadvantaged Farmer or Rancher (SDFR): In Brief
(March 19, 2021), available at https://crsreports.congress.gov/product/pdf/R/R46727/6.
\94\ See, e.g., Native American Business Development Act, 25
U.S.C. 4301(a).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The definitions and coverage in these statutes varies to some
extent. Some focus principally on members of groups that have
experienced racial or ethnic prejudices, while others include gender
prejudices. Additionally, some provide further assistance to new and
beginning farmers and military service veterans who are farmers. In
sum, these statutes reflect the now multi-decade priority of U.S.
agricultural policy to overcome barriers that stand in the way of full
market access for all producers and growers, with significant emphasis
placed on overcoming certain persistent forms of racial, ethnic, and
gender prejudices that obstruct full market access for some producers.
In interpreting the P&S Act, AMS has sought to propose a rule that
would remove barriers to market access for producers and growers most
vulnerable to being denied access. For the purposes of this proposed
rule, AMS is proposing a prohibition on undue prejudice on the basis of
a covered producer's membership in a vulnerable group. We seek comment
on whether to adopt one of several options for the term ``market
vulnerable individual,'' and if so, which one we should adopt. We are
also seeking comment on whether to specifically delineate certain
protected classes.
Because of the Act's broad application discussed in an earlier
section, ``II.B.i., Authority provided by the Act,'' the similar
language used in secs. 202, 304, 305, and 312 of the Act, and the
series of statutes outlining a range of prejudices identified as being
deserving of public policy efforts to ensure full market access, AMS
finds it reasonable that members of groups who have been subjected to
discrimination, prejudice, disadvantage, or exclusion on the basis of
race, ethnicity, or gender should be considered vulnerable and covered
by the prohibitions against undue prejudice or disadvantage and unjust
discrimination as enumerated by sec. 202 of the Act.
AMS is proposing, and seeking comment on, whether a flexible
definition of vulnerable group would be advantageous to ensuring
inclusive market access for covered producers by permitting an evolving
as well as market-specific application of the regulation. Such an
approach could address barriers to inclusion as they may arise. At the
same time, AMS is seeking comment on how to ensure that most persons
that would be protected under the Statement of General Policy and under
USDA's general regulations prohibiting discrimination, as noted above,
could be protected under this regulation.\95\ In particular, as noted
above AMS seeks comment on whether to delineate certain specific groups
as examples of market vulnerable groups, and also seeks comment on
whether it is preferable instead to prohibit discrimination based on
protected classes, such as on the basis of race, color, national
origin, religion, sex, sexual orientation, gender identity, age,
disability, marital status, and family status. AMS seeks additional
comment on the appropriate approach to protect market access for and
stop unjust discrimination against Indian tribes and tribal members.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\95\ See, e.g., Pregnancy Discrimination Act, see also Bostock
v. Clayton Cnty., Georgia, 140 S. Ct. at 1741.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Refusing to deal, providing less compensation, or any other type of
discrimination because of a person's particular non-economic
characteristics is the type of behavior both the Act and USDA aim to
prevent.
C. Cooperatives--Proposed Sec. 201.304(a)(1)
Proposed Sec. 201.304(a)(1) also specifies that regulated
entities, which include packers, swine contractors, or live poultry
dealers, may not discriminate against a cooperative of covered
producers--i.e., covered producers who collectively work together. For
example, individual covered producers may form a cooperative to meet
volume or other contractual requirements when they may not be able to
meet those requirements by themselves. A covered producer is defined in
the proposed regulations at Sec. 201.302 as a livestock producer as
defined in this section or swine production contract grower or poultry
grower as defined in section 2(a) of the Act. Covered producers acting
as a cooperative are an association or group made up of one or more
producers collectively processing, preparing for market, handling, and
marketing livestock or poultry. The P&S Act includes cooperative
associations in the definition of ``person'' at 7 U.S.C. 182(1),
providing that when used in the Act ``[t]he term ``person'' includes
individuals, partnerships, corporations, and associations. . .''
Covered producer cooperatives improve economic conditions for
individual producers. They have been demonstrated to be competitive and
responsive to meeting the needs of regulated entities and the
market.\96\ For example, smaller livestock producers may move towards
cooperative agreements on a regional basis to meet buyers' volume
requirements.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\96\ At least some of the drafters of the Act fully expected the
Act to be consonant to the goals of cooperatives: ``My own
conviction is that the cooperative effort of producers and consumers
to get closer together in an effort to reduce the spread between
them is the most favorable tendency of our time, so far as the
question of marketing and distribution is concerned.'' 61 Cong. Rec.
1882 (1921).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Producers have indicated to AMS that they feel such a move is
necessary, owing to the rise of concentration in the markets and the
decline in options for smaller producers. Small cattle producers have
expressed their concerns to AMS about disparate treatment by packers
between large and small producers. Large packers have commonly shown
limited interest in dealing with producers that operate on a smaller
capacity. On this point, producers have informed AMS that packers are
in search of deals with large quantities of product, and if a producer
is unable to meet demand for readily available bulk quantities, that
producer is unable to compete in the industry.
[[Page 60024]]
Producers testified in 2010 about packer buyers pulling out of
their small-scale feedlots for months in retaliation for producers
seeking higher prices and not allotting their entire herd capacity.
Packer buyers often prefer to include large quantities on single
transactions to lower transactions costs and maximize profits.\97\
Adding protections for smaller producers that wish to work together to
form cooperatives would enable smaller producers to (1) form
cooperatives without fear of prejudice or disadvantage, and (2) reduce
transactions costs for individual member producers.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\97\ U.S. Department of Justice & U.S. Department of
Agriculture, Public Workshops, Exploring Competition Issues in
Agriculture Livestock Workshop: A Dialogue on Competition Issues
Facing Farmers in Today's Agricultural Marketplaces, Fort Collins,
Colorado, August 27, 2010. Available at https://www.justice.gov/sites/default/files/atr/legacy/2012/08/20/colorado-agworkshop-transcript.pdf.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
This proposed regulation is intended, in part, to benefit smaller
producers--who lack the necessary land, capital, or financing (or for
other reasons may not wish) to establish a large enough operation to
meet preferred contractual requirements--by preventing discrimination
against their cooperative operations. Through cooperation, one or more
producers may be able to jointly meet the requirements and participate
as a producer in the industry, allowing producers to operate more
efficiently. Preventing discrimination against producer cooperatives
will provide another avenue for producers who otherwise might not have
been able to participate in the market.
While this section proposes that regulated entities may not
prejudice or disadvantage cooperatives of covered producers, based on
their protected status as a cooperative under this regulation, AMS
notes that regulated entities may decline contracting with cooperatives
for other justified economic reasons--i.e., for reasons other than the
prospective business partner's status as a cooperative. For example, a
regulated entity may refuse to contract with a cooperative of covered
producers when the contract would not be cost-effective for the entity,
regardless of the cooperative status of the producers. In this
hypothetical example, the regulated entity would not be unduly
prejudicing cooperatives of covered producers based on their status as
a cooperative. Instead, the regulated entity would have a
nonprejudicial basis for their business decision. AMS notes that
antitrust laws also prohibit cooperatives themselves from participating
in certain anticompetitive behavior. As discussed earlier, undue
prejudice and disadvantage may inhibit producers' ability to obtain
fair market value for their livestock and poultry and would be
prohibited under proposed Sec. 201.304(a)(1). Proposed Sec.
201.304(a)(1) aims to encourage a diverse agricultural market and
prevent undue prejudice and disadvantage and unjust discrimination
against cooperatives.
Congress has long protected cooperatives in the agricultural space,
acknowledging the need for farmers to meet the economic demands of the
market. One year after the passage of the P&S Act, Congress passed the
Capper-Volstead Act (Pub. L. 67-146), which permits producer
cooperatives to collectively process, prepare for market, handle, and
market their products. In a decision related to an antitrust action
against a nonprofit cooperative association whose members were involved
in production and marketing of broiler chickens, the Supreme Court
noted that farmers faced special challenges in the agricultural market
and therefore cooperatives are afforded legal protections in helping
them address those challenges.\98\ Congress also passed the
Agricultural Fair Practices Act,\99\ which provides enhanced
protections to those seeking to form a cooperative. In particular, that
statute prevents handlers from performing certain types of pricing and
contract discrimination, coercion, and other practices that undermine
cooperatives.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\98\ Nat'l Broiler Mktg. Ass'n v. United States, 436 U.S. 816,
825-26, 98 S. Ct. 2122, 2129, 56 L. Ed. 2d 728 (1978) (``Farmers
were perceived to be in a particularly harsh economic position. They
were subject to the vagaries of market conditions that plague
agriculture generally, and they had no means individually of
responding to those conditions. Often the farmer had little choice
about who his buyer would be and when he would sell. A large portion
of an entire year's labor devoted to the production of a crop could
be lost if the farmer were forced to bring his harvest to market at
an unfavorable time. Few farmers, however, so long as they could act
only individually, had sufficient economic power to wait out an
unfavorable situation. Farmers were seen as being caught in the
hands of processors and distributors who, because of their position
in the market and their relative economic strength, were able to
take from the farmer a good share of whatever profits might be
available from agricultural production. By allowing farmers to join
together in cooperatives, Congress hoped to bolster their market
strength and to improve their ability to weather adverse economic
periods and to deal with processors and distributors.'').
\99\ Public Law 90-288, Apr. 16, 1968, 82 Stat. 93 (7 U.S.C.
2301 et seq.).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
This proposed rule would provide additional protection for
cooperatives by preventing a regulated entity from isolating
cooperatives through contract termination and preventing cooperatives
from accessing markets for their products. As noted above, the P&S Act
intended to improve the agricultural market and includes associations
in the definition of ``person'' when referred to in the Act. The Act
affords cooperative associations the same protections against
discrimination as are afforded to all other covered producers. 7 U.S.C.
182(1). Thus, protections for cooperatives against discrimination were
contemplated at the time of the Act's passage.\100\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\100\ H.Rep. No. 85-1048, 1957.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
D. Enumerated Prejudices
Proposed Sec. 201.302(a)(2) outlines an inexhaustive list of
prejudices that, if based upon the covered producer's status, the
regulation prohibits. The harm that may be done through discriminatory
actions cannot be neatly cataloged, but the proposed Sec.
201.302(a)(2) sets forth injuries that the agency believes are
inherently prejudicial: offering less favorable terms, refusing to
deal, differential contract enforcement, and contract termination or
non-renewal. Under proposed Sec. 201.302(b), prejudicial actions are
to be considered together with the covered producer's membership in a
market vulnerable group or cooperative, and they would not by
themselves be violations. AMS seeks comment on the scope of these acts.
E. Retaliation
i. Retaliation as Discrimination Under the Act
Proposed Sec. 201.304(b) would establish protected activities for
covered producers and would prohibit regulated entities from
retaliatory conduct on the basis of those activities. Regulated
entities wield significant economic power given their vertical
relationships with producers. Regulated entities choosing to
discriminate among producers using their market power advantages for
the purpose of preventing certain producers, or groups of producers,
from engaging in the behaviors and activities discussed below, is
disparate treatment that is unjustly discriminatory. This type of
discrimination is oftentimes exercised through retaliation. The method
of retaliation may take many forms. Accordingly, the proposed rule is
designed to prohibit a variety of adverse actions. However, the
proposed regulations are also narrowly tailored, requiring the adverse
action to be linked to specific protected activities. Adverse actions
not tied to the activities
[[Page 60025]]
proposed would not be regulated under this proposal.
ii. Economic Rationale
While the statute does not require market-wide harm as a condition
to forbid retaliation, which is an abuse that undermines market
integrity, this section explains the adverse economic effects of
retaliation, which include harm across the marketplace. Indeed,
oligopsonistic or monopsonistic market structures can allow firms with
large market shares to use their market power advantage to punish
certain producer behaviors that the firm believes could offset their
market power advantage or even to punish producer behaviors that are
unrelated to the product or service they provide. When firms retaliate
by canceling contracts, selectively enforcing contract terms, renewing
contracts with unfavorable terms for the producer, or otherwise
impairing producers' ability to remain economically competitive as a
penalty for their engagement in the activities identified in the next
section, that conduct likely results in economic inefficiencies and
should be prohibited on a market wide basis, even if the specific
retaliatory act only affects one individual. Such impacts are
especially difficult to address when those firms maintain dominant
positions in the markets.
Retaliation against even one seller could presumably have a market-
wide chilling effect on others (at least within the area where the
retaliating entity is dominant). However, the ability to use such a
tool does require the right conditions, such as those that exist in
concentrated livestock markets where, in many cases, few or one firm
hold a dominate position. It is unlikely that packers or poultry
dealers operating in highly competitive markets (in which they are not
in a dominant economic position) could effectively use retaliation,
since livestock producers could simply find other buyers with whom to
do business.
Economic measures of firm concentration may help to identify when
retaliation may be more easily employed in a market, albeit noting that
an empirical relationship between retaliation and concentration
measures in livestock markets has not been established.
The following table shows the level of concentration in the
livestock and poultry slaughtering industries for 2010-2020 using four-
firm Concentration Ratios (CR4).
Table 2--Four-Firm Concentration Ratio in Livestock and Poultry Slaughter \101\
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Steers &
Year heifers (%) Hogs (%) Broilers (%) Turkeys (%)
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
2010............................................ 85 65 51 56
2011............................................ 85 64 52 55
2012............................................ 85 64 51 53
2013............................................ 85 64 54 53
2014............................................ 83 62 51 58
2015............................................ 85 66 51 57
2016............................................ 84 66 50 57
2017............................................ 83 66 51 53
2018............................................ 84 70 54 55
2019............................................ 85 67 53 55
2020............................................ 81 64 53 55
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
The table shows the combined market share of the four largest steer
and heifer slaughterers remained stable between 83 and 85 percent from
2010 to 2019 and dropped to 81 percent in 2020. Four-firm concentration
ratios for hog and broiler slaughter has also remained relatively
stable between 62 and 70 percent and 51 and 54 percent, respectively.
The data above are estimates of national four-firm concentration ratios
at the national level, but the relevant economic markets for livestock
and poultry may be regional or local, and concentration in the relevant
market may be higher than the national level.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\101\ U.S. Department of Agriculture, AMS Packers and Stockyards
annual reports. Available at https://www.ams.usda.gov/reports/psd-annual-reports (last accessed 8/9/2022).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
As discussed previously, regional concentration is often higher
than national concentration for hogs.\102\ Based on AMS's experience
conducting investigations and monitoring cattle markets, there are
commonly only one or two buyers in some local geographic markets, and
few sellers have the option of selling fed cattle to more than three or
four packers.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\102\ Wise, T. A., S. E. Trist. ``Buyer Power in U.S. Hog
Markets: A Critical Review of the Literature,'' Tufts University,
Global Development and Environment Institute (GDAE) Working Paper
No. 10-04, August 2010, available at: https://sites.tufts.edu/gdae/files/2020/03/10-04HogBuyerPower.pdf.TAbl (last accessed 8/9/2022).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Though poultry markets may appear to be the least concentrated in
terms of their national four-firm concentration ratios, relevant
economic markets for poultry growing services are more localized than
markets for fed cattle or hogs, and local concentration in poultry
markets is often greater than in hog and other livestock markets. The
following table highlights this issue by showing the limited ability a
poultry grower has to switch to a different integrator using the
Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI).\103\ Similar to a CR4, HHI is an
indicator of market concentration, with the index being increasing as
market shares across firms (packers) become more unequal and/or the
number of these firms decrease. Markets with HHIs above 2,500 are in
some cases considered highly concentrated. The following table is a
modification of a table in MacDonald (2104), adding HHI indices to the
latter's calculations of the integrators in the broiler grower's
geographic region. The HHIs in the table assume equal market share for
each integrator, and as such are the minimum HHIs possible (at least
with 2 to 4 growers). They show that 88.4% (72.2%) of growers are
facing an integrator HHI of at least 2,500 (3,333). The data suggests
that the majority of contract broiler growers in the U.S. are in
markets where the sellers have the potential for market power
advantage.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\103\ MacDonald, James M., and Nigel Key. ``Market power in
poultry production contracting? Evidence from a farm survey.''
Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics 44, no. 4 (2012): 477-
490.
[[Page 60026]]
Table 3--Integrators in the Broiler Growers' Region and Associated Market Power Indices
--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Minimum HHI of
Integrators in grower's area integrators in Farms Birds Production Can change to
grower's area another integrator
--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Number Percent of total Percent of farms
--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
1.................................................................. 10,000 21.7 23.4 24.5 7
2.................................................................. 5,000 30.2 31.9 31.7 52
3.................................................................. 3,333 20.4 20.4 19.7 62
4.................................................................. 2,500 16.1 14.9 14.8 71
>4................................................................. .............. 7.8 6.7 6.6 77
No Response........................................................ .............. 3.8 2.7 2.7 NA
--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Retaliation by oligopolistic or monopolistic firms can be
effectuated in the pursuit of economic self-interest or be done against
such interest for some nonpecuniary reason.\104\ In the case of
economic self-interest, oligopsonistic or monopsonistic integrators or
packers may use retaliation to facilitate their ability to earn excess
rents. However, this use of retaliation, as a means to protect excess
profits, is only possible when markets for livestock are characterized
by few integrators or packers. Where producers have few, if any,
alternative packers, or integrators to engage with, the act of not
renewing a contract, as retaliation for unfavorable behavior or
actions, can cause economic inefficiencies.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\104\ Fehr, Ernst, and Simon G[auml]chter. ``Fairness and
retaliation: The economics of reciprocity.'' Journal of economic
perspectives 14, no. 3 (2000): 159-181.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Retaliation may also be used by integrators and packers to ensure
that regulators or new entrants cannot discipline their behavior in the
marketplace. Both regulators and new entrants may be inhibited by the
inability to communicate with market participants. Regulators may be
unable to obtain the information needed to learn of or establish
violations, while prospective new entrants may be unable to establish
necessary market relationships with industry participants.
Many producers have expressed concerns about retaliatory behavior
from regulated entities with respect to activities inextricably
relevant to the livestock and poultry markets. Examples include
contract poultry and hog producers afraid to talk with USDA
representatives, file comments with USDA (or not file comments that
adopt their integrator's view), seek enforcement of contracts, organize
associations, or even attend association meetings, opt out of
arbitration, complain about feed outages and company personnel
behavior, and question the need for farm upgrades.\105\ In cattle and
independent hog production, private complaints to AMS include fear that
packers will refuse to visit farms or feedlots, offer bids on
livestock, purchase livestock from disfavored producers, and other more
subtle behaviors, like delaying delivery or shipment and manipulating
where producers fall in order of procurement.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\105\ U.S. Department of Justice & U.S. Department of
Agriculture, Public Workshops Exploring Competition in Agriculture,
Poultry Workshop, May 21, 2010, Alabama A&M University Normal,
Alabama. Available at Poultry Workshop Transcript (justice.gov).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
In addition, it is also possible that discriminatory or retaliatory
acts by packers or integrators intended to prevent the transfer of
rents also negatively affect efficiency by reducing the incentives for
investment, beneficial coordination of actions, or adoption of
innovative production process. In one case, a court found that an
integrator retaliated against a grower who was a leader of a growers'
association,\106\ suggesting both that producer coordination may reduce
the packers'/integrators' oligopsony excess profit and that growers'
ability to compete in these markets may be harmed by retaliation. In
another court case, James v. Tyson Foods, Inc., fifty-four poultry
growers sued the integrator for retaliatory actions and were awarded
$10 million in damages as a result.\107\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\106\ Terry v. Tyson Farms, Inc., 604 F.3d 272 (6th Cir. 2010).
\107\ James v. Tyson Foods, Inc., 292 P.3d 10 (Okla., 2012).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
F. Prohibition on Retaliation--Proposed Sec. 201.304(b)
To address the dangers of the retaliatory practices described
above, AMS is proposing to add Sec. 201.304(b) to the regulations.
Proposed Sec. 201.304(b)(1) would prohibit and provide examples of
retaliatory practices by regulated entities against covered producers
who engage in protected activities. Proposed Sec. 201.304(b)(2)(i)
through (vi) lists these protected activities.
Under Sec. 201.304(b)(1), regulated entities would be prohibited
from retaliating or otherwise taking an adverse action against a
covered producer because the covered producer participated in the
activities described in Sec. 201.304(b), to the extent that these
activities are not otherwise prohibited by Federal or state antitrust
laws. While a group of producers might be protected from retaliation
when associating in the production or marketing of livestock, producers
would not be protected from the adverse action of packers if the
producers engaged in a violation of Federal or state antitrust law. AMS
expects that prohibited retaliation would include, but not be limited
to termination of contracts, non-renewal of contracts, refusing to deal
with a covered producer, and interference in farm real estate
transactions or contracts with third parties. The proposed rule is
designed to prohibit all such actions with an adverse impact on a
covered producer.
AMS has chosen these specific examples of retaliation because they
represent the retaliatory practices that have been the most common
causes for complaints or because AMS has otherwise determined them to
be recurring problems in the livestock and poultry industries. Covered
producers have experienced termination or non-renewal of their
contracts for numerous reasons. Covered producers who have not
personally experienced these forms of retaliation have nevertheless
expressed fear of such retaliation through direct communication with
AMS personnel, at workshops, and in comments on previous related
rulemakings. Related to termination and non-renewal of contracts is a
regulated entity's refusal to deal. This proposed rule extends
protections against retaliation to covered producers who are refused a
new contract due to their involvement in protected activities. A
regulated entity would also be prohibited from interfering in a covered
producer's farm real estate transactions
[[Page 60027]]
or contracts with third parties. Impeding or obstructing a covered
producer's attempts to sell his or her farm or ability to contract with
a third party as a result of his or her participation in certain
activities hinders a covered producer's ability to freely participate
in the market. AMS believes that punishing covered producers or denying
them opportunities afforded to other covered producers because they
engaged in certain activities is an unjustly discriminatory practice.
Not only do retaliatory practices harm individual covered producers;
recurrent instances and patterns of retaliation erode market integrity
and discourage fairness and competition in the livestock and poultry
markets.
The specific examples of retaliatory practices listed in the
proposed regulation are not meant to be exhaustive; other retaliatory
actions with an adverse impact on covered producers would be prohibited
as well. When investigating complaints of retaliatory practices that do
not conform to one of these examples, AMS would, as it has in the past,
continue to use its expertise to determine whether a regulated entity's
action has an adverse impact on the covered producer.
G. Bases for Protected Activities--Proposed Sec. 201.304(b)
AMS has identified three categories of producer activities that we
propose to be protected due to concerns about retaliatory behavior from
packers, live poultry dealers, and swine contractors. Starting with the
recognition that these activities are related to the business of being
a producer or grower or involvement in that sectoral or geographic
community, the criteria used to establish the three categories--
consistent with the Act's purpose to safeguard farmers and ranchers
against receiving less than the true market value of their livestock
\108\--include the extent to which the activities are supported under
existing legal doctrine and the activities' potential to mitigate
market power abuses or enhance economic efficiency. The following
sections discuss three categories of protected activities: (i)
assertion of rights, (ii) associational participation, and (iii) lawful
communication, in the context of the criteria.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\108\ Stafford v. Wallace, 258 U.S. 495 (1922).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
i. Assertion of Rights
The basis of rights in this context is two-fold, including both
legal rights derived under various statutes and contractual rights
contained in agreements with regulated entities. Assertions of rights
may be necessary to ensure that covered producers are receiving
appropriate treatment in their dealings with regulated entities.
Disputes relating to contract terms and legal compliance could be over
differences between the buyer and seller over what constitutes mutually
agreeable returns or could even be over issues extraneous to the actual
product or service provided by the covered producer. Access to existing
legal remedies under state and Federal law may be necessary for covered
producers to effectuate their bargained-for exchange in contracting and
to address their inability to make complete contracts and associated
hold-up risk, which leads to under investment and less efficient market
allocations. Hold-up is the risk growers face at the time of contract
renewal when integrators make contract renewal dependent on further
grower investments not disclosed at the time of the original
agreements.\109\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\109\ Vukina, Tom, and Porametr Leegomonchai. ``Oligopsony
Power, Asset Specificity, and Hold-Up: Evidence from the Broiler
Industry.'' American Journal of Agricultural Economics 88 (2006).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Some regulated entities may prefer to limit, minimize, or otherwise
eliminate producer assertions or legal and contractual rights, as they
are likely associated with additional economic costs. For example, a
poultry grower may seek to enforce a production contract term providing
the grower with the right to five flocks annually, when the grower only
received four flocks. If a regulated entity sought to punish a grower
seeking enforcement of this term, the grower's risk of contract
termination would likely outweigh the benefit to them of contract
enforcement, and thereby undermine their contract, from the grower's
perspective. On the other hand, the regulated entity's cost of
breaching or terminating the agreement may be lower than their cost of
performance under the contract. Systemic conduct of this type would be
an abuse of market power and result in reduced allocative efficiency.
Attempts to limit, deter, or curtail producers' assertions of rights
mitigates or removes a primary producer tool for proper enforcement of
their rights.
ii. Associational Participation
While individual producers and growers operate at a tremendous
informational deficit compared to the larger sophisticated packer
operations, producer and grower organizations and associations can
mitigate incomplete and asymmetric information frictions in the market.
Producer and grower organizations may provide individual covered
producers the opportunity to counter other market power imbalances that
exist in the livestock and poultry industries. Associational
participation is connected to the provision of the product or service
of growing poultry or raising livestock and can serve to improve
producer productivity. Agriculture associations and organizations have
historically been favored under Federal \110\ and state laws and
exempted from certain types of Federal antitrust violations under the
Capper-Volstead Act.\111\ By narrowing the asymmetrical information gap
and creating other benefits, associations can enhance production and
allocative efficiencies.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\110\ See 7 U.S.C. 2301; 7 U.S.C. 291. The Agriculture Fair
Practices Act prevents agricultural handlers from discrimination and
coercion against individuals who belong to cooperatives. Among other
things, this statute prohibits handlers from undermining a
cooperative's ordinary operations by either bribing members of the
cooperative or making false reports about the cooperative's
operations.
\111\ For example, under Missouri's Nonprofit Cooperative
Marketing Law, RSMo 1939 section 14362, a nonprofit cooperative is
exempt from a number of taxes (including sales tax), and only pay an
annual fee of ten dollars.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Growers have expressed concern that associations and organizations
have repeatedly been targets of retaliatory behavior, and in some
instances, USDA and DOJ have intervened under the P&S Act. In the
1960s, poultry growers in Arkansas and Mississippi joined organizations
to try to advance their interests and protections in their contracts
with poultry companies. The poultry companies with which they had
contracts engaged in harassment, threats, intimidation, and retaliation
against the associations and the growers that joined them. A USDA
Administrative Law Judge held that the poultry companies' conduct was a
violation of the P&S Act and ordered the companies to cease and desist
from their unlawful actions and reinstate the growers who were
retaliated against.\112\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\112\ See In re: Arkansas Valley Industries, Inc., Ralston
Purina Company, and Tyson's Foods, Inc., 27 Ag. Dec. 84 (January 23,
1968), and In Re: Curtis Davis, Leon Davis, and Moody Davis d/b/a
Pelahatchie Poultry Company, 28 Ag. Dec. 406 (April 3, 1969).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
In 1989, a company operating a poultry slaughtering complex in
northern Florida, terminated its contract with a poultry grower who was
the president of a poultry growers' association. The U.S. District
Court issued an injunction against the company, finding that it acted
to hamper legal action by the growers' association and to discourage
other growers from presenting grievances to
[[Page 60028]]
governmental authorities. USDA and DOJ filed a lawsuit,along with
poultry growers, to enjoin the company's actions as constituting an
unfair, unjustly discriminatory, and deceptive practice and device, and
an undue and unreasonable prejudice and disadvantage, in violation of
the P&S Act.\113\ The Court agreed and also determined that the
company's actions would constitute obstruction of justice, extortion,
mail fraud, and wire fraud in furtherance of a pattern of racketeering
activity.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\113\ Baldree v. Cargill, Inc. and United States v. Cargill,
Inc., et al., 758 F.Supp.704 (M.D.Fla. 1990)
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
In these cases, courts determined that attempts to limit, deter, or
curtail associational participation limits lawful information exchanges
and prevents or dilutes the potential for covered producers to engage
in pro-competitive collaboration. This proposed regulation seeks to
codify this line of analysis, which has arisen under direct enforcement
of the statutory terms, and in the face of more recent court decisions
involving private litigation, to provide clarity to market participants
regarding USDA enforcement priorities going forward.\114\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\114\ See, e.g., Terry v. Tyson Farms Inc. 604 F.3d 272, 275
(6th Cir. 2009). On these line of cases, see also Michael Kades,
``Protecting Livestock Producers and Chicken Growers,'' Washington
Center for Equitable Growth (May 5, 2022), available at https://equitablegrowth.org/research-paper/protecting-livestock-producers-and-chicken-growers/.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
iii. Lawful Communications
Under this proposed rule, covered producer communications would
include any lawful communications with government agencies or other
persons for the purpose of improving the production or marketing of
livestock or poultry, exploring a possible business relationship, or
supporting proceedings under the Act against a regulated entity.
Broadly, these types of communication improve transparency, facilitate
compliance with and enforcement of relevant laws and regulations, and
can serve to mitigate market power abuse and enhance production and
allocative efficiencies, as well as protect market integrity.
Communications With Government Agencies and Communications Related to
Proceedings Under the Act
Related to ``assertions of rights,'' covered producers seeking the
enforcement of a regulatory scheme designed to benefit them will likely
need to communicate with government representatives. This communication
is only incidental to the product or service provided to the regulated
entity, and communication with government representatives serves
numerous public policy interests. Abuses of market power to restrict
communication related to government compliance programs would
systematically result in deprivation of legal rights, losses in income
or welfare for producers, and costs to markets and society.\115\
Covered producers have expressed concerns regarding their
communications with government agencies and support for government
actions. For example: a cattle producer believes he has been the victim
of weight fraud by a regulated entity, but as a producer with limited
alternative outlets for sale of his cattle, the producer may be
hesitant to report the fraud to USDA or other authorities for fear the
regulated entity will refuse to engage in future business.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\115\ Heese, Jonas, and Gerardo P[eacute]rez-Cavazos. ``The
effect of retaliation costs on employee whistleblowing.'' Journal of
Accounting and Economics 71, no. 2-3 (2021): 101385. European
Commission, Directorate-General for Internal Market, Industry,
Entrepreneurship and SMEs, Rossi, L., McGuinn, J., Fernandes, M.,
Estimating the economic benefits of whistleblower protection in
public procurement: final report, Publications Office, 2017, https://data.europa.eu/doi/10.2873/125033 (last accessed Aug. 2022).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Communications for the Purpose of Improving Production/Marketing or
Exploring a Business Relationship
As with communications related to enforcement, communications for
the purpose of improving production or marketing or exploring business
relationships aid covered producers in obtaining fair market value for
their livestock and poultry. Protecting such communications would
protect the producer's ability to obtain help from experts and
professionals unaffiliated with the regulated entity. In addition,
covered producers would be able to explore business opportunities
without fear of reprisal from firms with which they currently do
business. Communications of this type can improve production efficiency
and price discovery mechanisms.
Retaliatory actions can also result from a blend of protected
activities. In Philson v. Cold Creek Farms, Inc., turkey growers
alleged in part that the poultry company provided them with lower
quality poults than it provided to other growers, and that the
company's motivation for doing that was to punish and discourage
growers from voicing their complaints (lawful communication) about the
company's practices. Some of the turkey growers also alleged that their
poultry contracts were terminated in retaliation for their objections
to the poultry company's weighing and computing practices (assertion of
rights). The Court noted that ``[s]uch a retaliatory act is properly
challenged under the PSA as it adversely affects competition and could
be considered unfair, unjustly discriminatory or deceptive.'' \116\
Here, we see retaliation related to two categories of protected
activities.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\116\ Philson v. Cold Creek Farms, Inc., 947 F. Supp. 197 at 202
(E.D.N.C. 1996).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
H. Delineation of Protected Activities
Paragraphs (b)(2)(i) through (vi) of proposed Sec. 201.304 list
activities that would be protected. Regulated entities would be
prohibited from retaliating against covered producers due to the
covered producer's participation in these protected activities. AMS has
determined that a covered producer's ability to freely participate in
these activities without fear of retaliation is essential to promoting
fair and competitive markets in the livestock and poultry industries.
Many of these activities also represent activities for which covered
producers have experienced or expressed fear of retaliation.
Specifically, proposed paragraph (b)(2)(i) would protect a covered
producer's ability to communicate with a government agency regarding
the production of poultry or livestock, or to petition for redress of
grievances before a court, legislature, or government agency. A covered
producer's ability to communicate with a government agency is an
essential tool for ensuring that a covered producer's rights are
protected. Likewise, a covered producer must be able to freely petition
for the redress of grievances for the protections afforded to covered
producers by laws and regulations to have their intended effect.
Proposed paragraph (b)(2)(ii) would protect a covered producer's
ability to assert any of the rights granted under the Act or the
regulations in 9 CFR part 201, or to assert rights afforded by their
contact. These rights include, for example, growers' rights to view the
weighing of flocks, which is legally protected but which growers have
complained is not practically enforceable. Although these rights are
ostensibly protected by laws, regulations, or legal contracts, they
lose their efficacy if covered producers suffer repercussions for
asserting them.
Proposed paragraph (b)(2)(iii) would protect a covered producer's
ability to assert the right to formor joinaproducer or grower
association or organization, or to collectively process, prepare for
market, handle, or market livestock or poultry.An assertion of rights
in this context may involve expressing interest
[[Page 60029]]
or intent to engage in these activities or engaging in these
activities. Associations and organizations provide a means for covered
producers to share information regarding the production of poultry and
livestock, to potentially uncover recurrent problematic practices in
the industry, and to potentially organize to seek redress of
grievances, among other benefits. Collectively processing, preparing
for market, handling, or marketing livestock or poultry affords covered
producers the opportunity to combine their resources to potentially
counteract market imbalances. AMS believes that retaliating against
producers for engaging in these activities hinders the free flow of
information and hampers producers' ability to fairly compete in the
market.
Proposed paragraph (b)(2)(iv) would protect a covered producer's
ability to communicate or cooperate with a person for the purposes of
improving production or marketing of livestock or poultry. Such
communication may include, for example, communication with extension
programs or with independent veterinarians and animal health experts.
Proposed paragraph (b)(2)(v) would protect a covered producer's
ability to communicate or negotiate with a regulated entity for the
purposes of exploring a business relationship. A covered producer may
want to seek information from a regulated entity with which they do not
currently have a business relationship regarding the possibility of a
future business relationship, such as entering into a contract.
Protecting this activity would allow covered producers to freely
compare potential business relationships and choose between several
regulated entities, encouraging competition.
Finally, proposed paragraph (b)(2)(vi) would protect a covered
producer's ability to support or participate as a witness in any
proceeding under the Act or a proceeding that relates to an alleged
violation of law by a regulated entity. Owing to the close-knit and
concentrated markets in which covered producers operate, protecting
some covered producers as witnesses may enable other covered producers
to effectuate their rights under the Act and related laws. Without such
protections, enforcement of the Act may be frustrated overall.
I. Recordkeeping
To help lessen these threats of retaliation, the proposed rule
contains compliance systems for monitoring and facilitating compliance
and change within companies. Vital to such an effort will be AMS's
ability to inspect relevant records, as they may exist, such as
policies and procedures, staff training and producer information
materials, data and testing, board of directors' oversight materials,
and other relevant materials. AMS may utilize compliance inspections,
company reports to AMS, and public analyses to benchmark industry
practice and improve market standards. AMS believes that its
recordkeeping approach will enable it to monitor and facilitate a
regulated entity's approach to compliance at the highest levels,
including the tone at the top: chief executive officers and boards of
directors. The tone and compliance practices set by senior executives
can be expected to play a vital role in establishing a corporate
culture of compliance, which is a critical defense against legal and
regulatory violations and a first step towards more inclusive market
practices.
Proposed paragraph (c) would ensure appropriate recordkeeping
regarding compliance. It indicates certain specific records should be
kept for a period of 5 years. Specifically, regulated entities would be
required to retain, to the extent that they produce them, policies and
procedures, staff training materials, materials informing covered
producers about reporting mechanisms and protections, compliance
testing, board of directors' oversight materials, and records about the
number and nature of complaints received relevant to prejudice and
retaliation. AMS is proposing 5 years to provide a broader ability to
monitor the evolution of compliance practices over time in this area,
and to ensure that records are available for what may be complex
evidentiary cases.
Recordkeeping, as described in the proposed rule, is a commonly
utilized regulatory compliance and monitoring mechanism among market
regulators.\117\ Access to these records will assist AMS in assessing
the effectiveness of the regulated entity's compliance with Sec.
201.304. Existing gaps in both generally applicable agricultural and
PSD-specific data collection make addressing widespread reports of
discriminatory behavior difficult. Recordkeeping is critical if AMS is
to fulfill its duties to prevent and secure enforcement against undue
prejudice and unjust discrimination in the relevant agricultural
sector.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\117\ See, e.g., generally, Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System, ``Federal Trade Commission Act, Section 5: Unfair or
Deceptive Acts or Practices,'' Consumer Compliance Handbook,
available at https://www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/supmanual/cch/ftca.pdf (last accessed June 2022).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
J. Request for Comments on Proposed Sec. 201.304
AMS specifically invites comments on various aspects of the
proposal to prohibit undue prejudices and unjust discrimination as
described above. Please fully explain all views and alternative
solutions or suggestions, supplying examples and data or other
information to support those views where possible. Parties who wish to
comment anonymously may do so by entering ``N/A'' in the fields that
would identify the commenter. While comments on any aspect of the
proposed rule are welcome, AMS specifically solicits comments on the
following.
Undue Prejudices and Unjust Discrimination
1. Would the regulatory protections provided by the prohibition on
undue prejudices for market vulnerable individuals and cooperatives, as
described above, assist those producers and growers in overcoming
barriers to market access or equitable and reasonable treatment, or
otherwise address prejudices or the threat thereof in the marketplace?
If so, why? If not, why not?
2. With respect to undue prejudices, are the proposed prohibited
bases of market vulnerable individuals and cooperatives broad enough to
provide appropriate flexibility and ensure equitable market access? If
not, please suggest changes.
3. Should AMS delineate specific examples of groups that are market
vulnerable? If so, please provide supportive evidence regarding
historical adverse treatment of such groups.
4. Should AMS delineate specific forms of prejudice, such as
racial, ethnic, gender, or religious prejudices, that would apply for
producers who are members of the relevant group without regard to their
individual qualities?
5. Is the proposed list of undue prejudices appropriately clear and
inclusive--for example, is it sufficiently clear that prejudices
relating to gender include sexual orientation?
6. As an alternative or in addition to the market vulnerable
individual approach, should AMS prohibit discrimination based on
protected classes (i.e., prohibit discrimination on the basis of race,
color, national origin, religion, sex, sexual orientation, disability,
age, marital status, family/parental status, income derived from a
public assistance program, political
[[Page 60030]]
beliefs, or gender identity)? Why or why not?
7. Should prejudices be more specifically delineated in the
rulemaking to cover some or all of the bases governing non-
discrimination in conducted programs as discussed in the section on
specific proposed bases, and specifically: race, color, national
origin, religion, sex, sexual orientation, disability, age, marital
status, family/parental status, income derived from a public assistance
program, political beliefs, or gender identity? Why or why not?
8. With respect to undue prejudices, should localities be addressed
in any special way, such as localities where producers or growers are
underserved or otherwise face persistent challenges of equitable and
reasonable market access owing to the locality or related reasons?
Please provide specific examples, if possible.
9. What specific challenges or burdens may regulated entities face
in complying with the undue prejudices provisions of the proposed rule?
How do they differ from existing policies, procedures, and practices of
regulated entities?
10. Should AMS clarify how producers and growers demonstrate
qualification for the protections as market vulnerable individuals in a
local market? If so, what factors should be included?
11. Are the specific prejudicial acts specified in proposed Sec.
201.304(a)(2) appropriate? Are there additional forms of prejudicial
conduct that should be specifically delineated? If so, please identify
them and provide examples of how such actions have been used to target
market vulnerable individuals or cooperatives.
12. Are there different types of purchase arrangements than those
generally or ordinarily offered, such as forward contracts, formula
contracts, other alternative marketing agreements, or cash market
purchases, which could be employed in a prejudicial manner as a class
of contract or in specific circumstances? If so, please identify them
and provide examples of how such actions have been used to target
market vulnerable individuals or cooperatives.
13. Does the undue prejudices provision provide sufficient
protection regardless of the type of business organization of the
covered producer? If not, please suggest specific changes.
14. Should prejudicial discrimination and retaliation provisions be
extended to all persons buying or selling meat and meat food products,
including poultry, in markets subject to the Act? Why or why not?
15. Does the proposed rule appropriately enable the production of
religiously compliant meats? Do any concerns turn on whether the
prohibited prejudices in proposed Sec. 201.304(a)(1) are defined to
include religious bases? Please explain your views and suggest specific
approaches to address any concerns.
16. Do the provisions on undue prejudice adequately address
concerns regarding inequitable market access for Tribal members and
Tribes? If not, what additional changes should be proposed?
17. How should AMS handle Tribal government entities that sponsor
or manage regulated entities? Should AMS permit compliance with
proposed Sec. 201.304(a) be substituted for compliance with Tribal
government rules, policies, or guidance governing equitable market
access?
18. AMS is aware of at least one private industry program aimed at
establishing preferences intended to create ``a more equitable
agricultural economy''--in response to ``systemic inequality''--by
partnering with Black producers.\118\ Were such a program (or a similar
program designed to address socially inclusive supply chains) present
in livestock and poultry markets, should AMS evaluate and determine
that such program is an undue preference pursuant to the criteria set
forth in 9 CFR 201.211? Please explain views and offer suggestions on
ways to address relevant concerns.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\118\ Cargill's ``Black Farmer Equity Initiative'': https://www.cargill.com/about/black-farmer-equity-initiative (last accessed
8/9/2022).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
19. Does the proposed regulation provide appropriate protection for
cooperatives, in particular as the structure and organization of
cooperatives vary across livestock and poultry markets? Please explain
any particular concerns that should be better addressed by the proposed
regulation.
20. Prejudice and other prohibited actions the agency proposes
refers to offering contract terms that are less favorable than those
generally or ordinarily offered. Should the agency be more specific to
include differential contract terms, such as: price terms, including
any base or formula price; formulas used for premiums or discounts
related to grade, yield, quality, or specific characteristics of the
animals or meat; the duration of the commitment to purchase or to
contract for the production of animals; transportation requirements;
delivery location requirements; delivery date and time requirements;
terms related to who determines date of delivery; the required number
of animals to be delivered; layout periods in production contracts;
financing, risk-sharing, and profit-sharing; or terms related to the
companies' provision of inputs or services, grower compensation, and
capital investment requirements under production contracts? Please
explain why or why not, and what terms the agency could add or change.
21. Should the Agency include among the prejudices, the action of
offering less favorable price terms, contract terms, and other less
favorable treatment in the course of business dealings than those
generally offered to similarly situated producers? Should an allowance
be made for legitimate business reasons? Please explain why or why not,
and what terms the Agency could add or change.
Retaliation
22. Would the regulatory protections provided by the prohibition on
retaliation, as described above, assist producers and growers in
avoiding unjust discrimination in the market or otherwise help them
access markets, obtain meaningful and accurate price discovery, or
avoid anticompetitive or unjust practices or the threats thereof? If
so, why; if not, why not?
23. Are the specific acts of retaliation listed in proposed Sec.
201.304(b)(3) appropriate? Are there additional forms of retaliatory
conduct that should be specifically delineated?
24. Should prohibitions on retaliation protect producers and
growers who choose not to participate in protected activities? For
example, should the provision prohibit the giving of any premiums or
discounts with respect to joining or not joining livestock or poultry
associations?
25. Are the bases of protected activities appropriate, including
their nexus to the business, industry, and community, criteria for
selection, and application of those criteria? Should they be broader,
narrower, or different in some way? Please explain your views.
26. Should the protected activities relating to communication and
cooperation, beyond government entities, be limited to USDA extension
and USDA supported (grantees and cooperators) non-profit entities? Why
or why not?
27. Does the proposed anti-retaliation provision provide sufficient
protection regardless of the covered producer's type of business
organization? If not, please suggest specific changes.
28. Should protections for exploring a business relationship be
extended to such activities with any person, or
[[Page 60031]]
should they be limited, as they are in the proposal, to exploring a
business relationship with a regulated entity?
29. Should the proposed list of retaliatory actions include a
catch-all clause, such as ``offering unfavorable contract terms that
otherwise effect reprisal'' or ``offering contract terms that are less
favorable than those generally or ordinarily offered''? That is, is the
offering of a contract term a proper subject of retaliation? If so,
should we also include a non-exclusive list of contract terms that
could affect reprisal, such as price terms, including any base or
formula price; formulas used for premiums or discounts related to
grade, yield, quality, or specific characteristics of the animals or
meat; the duration of the commitment to purchase or to contract for the
production of animals; transportation requirements; delivery location
requirements; delivery date and time requirements; terms related to who
determines date of delivery; the required number of animals to be
delivered; layout periods in production contracts; financing, risk-
sharing, and profit-sharing; or terms related to the companies'
provision of inputs or services, grower compensation, or capital
investment requirements under production contracts? Please explain why
or why not, and what terms the agency could add or change.
30. What specific challenges or burdens might regulated entities
face in complying with the anti-retaliation provisions of the proposed
rule? How do the proposed provisions differ from existing policies,
procedures, and practices of regulated entities?
Recordkeeping
31. Are the recordkeeping obligations of the proposed regulation
appropriate to permit AMS to monitor regulated entities for compliance?
Why or why not, and what changes, if any, should be made?
32. Should AMS require regulated entities to produce and maintain
specific policies and procedures, specific compliance practices or
certifications, or specific disclosures to help ensure compliance with
the undue prejudices and anti-retaliation provisions of the proposed
rule? Please explain why for specific items.
33. What specific challenges or burdens might regulated entities
face in complying with recordkeeping duties of the proposed rule? How
do they differ from existing policies, procedures, and practices of
regulated entities?
III. Deceptive Practices
AMS also proposes a new Sec. 201.306 designed to prohibit
regulated entities from specified deceptive practices in contracting.
Because of the power of the regulated entities over their vertical
relationships, deceptions in contracting are of considerable concern.
Similar to its broad prohibition of unjustly discriminatory
practices, the Act does not specifically define the ``deceptive
practices'' it prohibits in sec. 202(a). The agency's interpretation of
``deceptive practices'' here relates to trends underlying the Act's
passage. At the time of the Act's passage, state common law already
prohibited deceptive practices, such as fraudulent inducement of
contract and misattribution of the source of goods. These are not, as
the Act is not, limited to deceived and injured contracting parties,
but also include deceptions that directly injure competitors.
Regardless, courts were cautiously expanding common law beyond
misrepresentations of source to misrepresentations concerning other
characteristics or qualities of the seller's goods.\119\ Likewise, in
1920--shortly before the passage of the Act--Congress passed a Federal
trademark law that prohibited intentional deception regarding the
origin of goods. Public Law 66-163, 41 Stat. 534 (1920). So, in 1921,
the Act was one of the earliest Federal prohibitions against deceptive
practices. It did not remain so for long.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\119\ Restatement (Third) of Unfair Competition sec. 2 (1995),
comment b.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Less than a decade after the passage of the Act, in 1930, the
Perishable Agricultural Commodities Act followed with its prohibitions
against ``deceptive practices in connection with the weighing,
counting, or in any way determining the quantity of any perishable
agricultural commodity received, bought, sold, shipped, or handled in
interstate or foreign commerce.'' See 7 U.S.C. 499b. In 1938, the
Federal Trade Commission Act was amended to declare unlawful
``deceptive acts or practices in or affecting commerce.'' Public Law
75-447, 52 Stat. 111 (1938). As observed in 1967, ``[d]eceptive trade
practices victimize honest merchants as well as consumers, and impair
rational allocation of economic resources.'' \120\ The FTC has
characterized deception as: involving a material representation,
omission or practice that is likely to mislead a consumer acting
reasonably in the circumstances.\121\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\120\ Richard F. Dole, Jr., Merchant and Consumer Protection:
The Uniform Deceptive Trade Practices Act, 76 Yale L.J. 485 (1967).
\121\ Federal Trade Commission, Policy Statement on Deception,
1983, available at https://www.ftc.gov/legal-library/browse/ftc-policy-statement-deception (last accessed Aug. 2022).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
``[I]ntegrity and ethics of those engaged in marketing livestock''
is a vital concern.\122\ With respect to regulating deception, the
supply of meat to the American consumer depends on a market that is
safe, reliable, and honest.\123\ Protecting the market from the harms
of deception starts with protecting suppliers: producers, market
agencies, dealers, and packers. To achieve a market free of deceptive
practices, the Secretary has established regulations and pursued
administrative and Federal enforcement cases.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\122\ See, e.g., Midwest Farmers v. United States, 64 F. Supp.
91, 95 (D. Minn. 1945).
\123\ In re: Frosty Morn Meats, Inc., 7 B.R. 988, 1020 (M.D.
Tenn. 1980).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
In the case law and through regulations, as described below,
violative deceptions under the Act include false statements or
omissions that occur even before contracting that prevent or mislead
sellers or buyers from making an informed decision. Thus, obvious
falsehoods, such as false weighing and false accounting have always
been considered deceptive practices under sec. 202(a) of the Act.
Another obvious falsehood, delivering checks drawn on accounts with
insufficient funds--whether for livestock or meat--is also deceptive.
Moreover, the Act requires honest dealing, so misleading omissions are
also prohibited. Prohibited omissions include failure to tell a
business partner that the regulated entity was receiving a commission
from a competitor, sales tactics that omit relevant information, or
failure to have the required bond. And finally, where regulated
entities have close business relationships, secret payments and bribes
undermine the ability of producers and consumers to rely on an honest
market and are therefore deceptive.
This proposed regulation would not be the first to prohibit
deception. Current Packers and Stockyards regulations require honesty
in weighing (Sec. Sec. 201.49, 201.71), price reporting (Sec.
201.53), fees (Sec. 201.98), and business relationships (Sec.
201.67). Even in the consideration of whether termination of a contract
violated the Act, AMS currently considers the quality of the
communication, and therefore considers its honesty. (See Sec.
201.217.)
Producers and consumers cannot make rational decisions in a
dishonest market, and honest competitors cannot compete when regulated
entities deceive. For example, if one packer is paying more for
livestock by weight but is also deceptively weighing livestock to lower
the total value of the livestock during processing, the honest packer
[[Page 60032]]
must compete with that deception. On the other hand, if the weight of
livestock from a packer were to be regularly more favorable, due to
falsely increasing the weight, honest competitors would have to respond
to a reputation that their weights are lower. A packer that fails to
pay for meat promptly is not only deceiving the seller--by financing
their operations using the seller's goods--but is also forcing honest
meat packers to compete without financing their operations in this
deceptive manner. Proposed Sec. 201.306--Deceptive practices--would
name practices and devices that AMS considers deceptive in violation of
sec. 202(a) of the Act, which prohibits deceptive practices and devices
by packers, swine contractors, and live poultry dealers. AMS intends
that this proposed regulation would address broad areas of specific
concern, but it may not exhaustively identify all deceptive practices
that would violate sec. 202(a) of the Act.
As outlined extensively in the separately proposed transparency
rule, poultry growers face incomplete information regarding contracting
and tournaments and have complained of inaccurate information
influencing their decisions to be growers or make additional capital
investments. While AMS has separately proposed specific disclosures
relating to transparency in poultry growing contracts and tournaments
in another proposed rule, Transparency in Poultry Growing Contracting
and Tournaments, 87 FR 34980 (June 8, 2022), the provisions of this
proposed rule are broader. These provisions also encompass poultry
growing contracting and tournaments; for example, this proposed rule
would address communications by the live poultry dealer and its agents
in the context of contracting or tournaments. Further, this rulemaking
addresses deception in hog and cattle markets, which is not addressed
in the proposed transparency rule.
The provisions of this proposed rule would also focus on general
circumstances that may give rise to the provision of false or
misleading information in the production or growing of poultry or
livestock. Such circumstances could include where a live poultry
dealer's poultry nutrition adviser provides misleading advice to a
contract grower, where a swine production contract provides false
information regarding manure compliance procedures, or where a packer
provides false or misleading information about cash market trading in
livestock.
These proposed provisions respond, in part, to the range of
complaints lodged with USDA, Congress, and the media over the years
regarding inaccurate, incomplete, or otherwise misleading
representations or pretexts that affect the decision-making or access
to markets by producers and growers of livestock and poultry. For
example, packers and industry representatives have routinely indicated
that producers may choose the form of pricing mechanism for their
transactions. However, as cash-negotiated markets have declined,
producers have increasingly complained to USDA that they are not
provided such a choice, and in fact are commonly given a take-it-or-
leave-it offer to buy their cattle off of a pricing formula provided by
the company. Producers have complained that they have been told their
cattle are not of sufficiently high quality or that formula market
arrangements are necessary to incentivize such quality, but cattle
procured under those marketing arrangements may not in fact be of any
higher quality. This raises legitimate concerns that certain refusals
to deal are based upon pretext or deception, which hinders the free
flow of livestock from producer to consumer. If producers have been
misled, they are hindered from organizing their operations so that they
can correctly identify competitor packers that will accept their
livestock or otherwise contract with them.
Poultry growers have complained over the years regarding
unfavorable provision of inputs made to certain producers despite
statements by live poultry dealers that there are no differences in
treatment. Growers have also complained of terminations, suspensions,
or reductions in flocks on the basis of pretext, such as animal welfare
contractual violations, when in fact other reasons may exist for the
termination, including but not limited to the discrimination and
retaliation noted above, or other unreasonable bases such as a
preference for family or friends of the local agent of a live poultry
dealer or for a poultry grower connected to a senior executive of a
live poultry dealer.\124\ If misleading information in connection with
a termination is provided to a bank that forecloses on the grower, this
may be actionable as well by the grower who was the victim of the
deception. While this would not necessarily be an undue preference or
unjust discrimination, it would be covered by this deception
rulemaking. Therefore, the proposed rule supports market integrity more
broadly by ensuring that producers and growers can make decisions and
operate in the market based on complete and accurate information.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\124\ Wheeler v. Pilgrim's Pride, 536 F.3d 455 (5th Cir. 2008).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Hog producers and growers, as well as cattle producers, have also
highlighted concerns regarding preferential market access for company-
owned or controlled livestock. Again, while this part of the proposed
rule would not prohibit undue preferences, this deception rulemaking
would establish a clearer duty on regulated entities regarding honesty
and market integrity in the relationships with covered producers,
including with respect to statements made regarding market access and
other aspects of contracting.
The high levels of oligopsony in the local marketplaces in which
many producers and growers operate today, and the extensive reliance on
vertical integration, forward contracting, and long-term marking
agreements, mean that producers and growers are more vulnerable to
being excluded from, or to suffering adverse pricing in, the
marketplace by these deceptions in contracting, if and where they may
arise.
More than 100 years of history illustrate the types of conduct
prohibited as deceptive by the Act, which provide a foundation for some
of the specific deceptions that this proposed rule addresses. The FTC
employed a similar approach when developing its policy on deceptive
practices. Recognizing that there was no single definitive statement of
the FTC's authority on ``deceptive acts or practices,'' it reviewed its
own history of decided cases to identify the most important principles
of general applicability and provide a greater sense of certainty as to
how the concept of deception will be applied. The FTC's approach
informs AMS in identifying and prohibiting deceptive practices. Past
cases indicate that USDA's approach, generally, is to view
representations, omissions, and practices from the perspective of a
reasonable party receiving them and determine if those deceptions
affect the conduct or decision of the recipient. As the court explained
in Gerace v. Utica Veal Co., 580 F. Supp. 1465, 1469 (N.D.N.Y. 1984),
regulated entities are liable to anyone for the damages they sustain in
consequence of an entity's deceptive practice, even if they are not a
direct party to the transaction.
AMS believes that a substantial arc of deceptive practices in the
marketplace that this specific rulemaking intends to prohibit can be
organized and summarized as deceptions in contract formation, contract
operation, contract cancellation, and refusals to contract.
[[Page 60033]]
Deceptions in the contracting process present harms that cause the type
of injury the Act was designed to prevent. This proposed regulation
addresses these four types of deceptions.
A. Scope of Deceptive Practices Regulated
Proposed Sec. 201.306(a), Deceptive practices, sets forth the
scope of the prohibition of deceptive practices in the rest of Sec.
201.306. The P&S Act limits the Secretary's jurisdiction to the
regulated entities' operations subject to the P&S Act. Thus, the
proposed regulation's scope relates to those operations with respect to
livestock, meats, meat food products, livestock products in
unmanufactured form, or live poultry.
B. Deceptive Practices in the Offering or Formation of Contract
Proposed Sec. 201.306(b) would prohibit a regulated entity from
making or modifying a contract when the entity employs a pretext, false
or misleading statement, or fails to state a material fact necessary to
make the statement made not otherwise false or misleading. Therefore,
this proposed regulation is intended to prevent deception in contract
offering or formation.
Deception in the offering or formation of a contract has taken many
forms through the Act's history. One example is false advertising,
specifically bait and switch advertising, which occurs through
advertising on price when, in fact, the customer has to pay a higher
price at the point of sale. This practice is illegal under both the P&S
Act and the FTC Act. In the case under the P&S Act, In re: Larry W.
Peterman, d/b/a Meat Masters, 42 Agric. Dec. 1848 (1983), aff'd
Peterman v. United States Dep't of Agric, 770 F.2d 888 (10th Cir.
1985), the packer advertised meat at a very attractive low price.
Customers responded to the advertised price, only to be subjected to
deceptive sales tactics, causing them to purchase higher priced meats.
The advertised meat was ``so fat [the customer] could see very little
red muscle tissue in it,'' causing the customer to purchase primal cuts
rather than what they intended to buy because the packer represented
that the fat loss and yield would be a better option. After their
purchase, customers determined that they had paid significantly more
than they were led to believe, and they could have paid much less even
at retail grocery stores.
Under certain circumstances, failures to disclose information are
also deceptive. The Act's purposes include protecting farmers and
ranchers from receiving less than fair market value for their livestock
and protecting consumers from unfair practices. Solomon Valley Feedlot,
Inc. v. Butz, 557 F.2d 717, 718 (10th Cir. 1977). ``Among the means
employed to accomplish this purpose is the use of surety bonds.'' Id.
at 720. Sellers of livestock are entitled to the protection of a
packer, dealer, or market agency's surety bond securing its
obligations. Failure to maintain an adequate bond is therefore a
deceptive practice.\125\ When a packer fails to maintain a bond, the
seller does not know that the sale is unsecured, and therefore the
seller is at greater risk of nonpayment.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\125\ United States v. Hulings, 484 F. Supp. 562, 567 (D. Kan.
1980). See also In Re: Mid-W. Veal Distributors, 43 Agric. Dec.
1124, 1139-40 (1984), citing In re: Norwich Veal and Beef, Inc., 38
Agric. Dec. 214 (1979), In Re: Raskin Packing Co., 37 Agric. Dec.
1890, 1894-6 (1978).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Deception in contract formation is not limited to false statements
and omissions with respect to regulatory requirements. The Act includes
affirmative duties to be truthful. For instance, a court has recognized
that the P&S Act prohibits a regulated entity from negotiating using
published prices it knows are inaccurate because using incorrect prices
deceives the livestock seller. See Schumacher v. Tyson Fresh Meats,
Inc., 434 F.Supp.2d 748 (Dist. S.D. 2006). In Schumacher, the packer
failed to disclose inaccurately reported boxed beef prices when it
negotiated the purchase of cattle on the basis of those prices. Because
the Act prohibits deceptive practices with respect to the price paid to
the producer, the court found that those deceptive practices do not
need to adversely affect competition to violate the Act. Id.
Likewise, Bruhn's Freezer Meats of Chicago, Inc. v. U.S. Dept. of
Agriculture, 438 F.2d 1332 (8th Cir. 1971), affirmed that a variety of
deceptions violate the Act, including short weighing, misrepresenting
grades and cuts of meat, and false advertising in the selling of meat
to customers. The agency's proposed regulation with respect to
deceptive practices in contract formation prohibits all these types of
deception.
More importantly, AMS is concerned that transparency in market
transactions--reported prices, offered contracts, and long-term
contracts--is inhibited by potentially deceptive practices and
statements. AMS has long received complaints regarding statements that
entice producers to contract to their eventual detriment. This
provision would make clear that statements at the time of contract
formation will be evaluated to determine if there is deception in order
to prevent injury to the producers in their inception.
C. Deceptive Practices in the Operation of Contract
Proposed Sec. 201.306(c) would prohibit a regulated entity from
performing under or enforcing a contract by employing a pretext, false
or misleading statement, or omission of a material fact necessary to
make the statement not false or misleading.
Deceptive practices take many forms throughout the operation of a
contract. USDA and the courts have recognized these forms in a variety
of administrative and Federal enforcement actions, including false
weighing, false or deceptive grading (including failure to disclose the
formulas for determining payment), commercial bribery, and failing to
pay for purchases.
False or inaccurate weighing has long been recognized as deceptive
under secs. 202(a) and 312 of the Act. See Bruhn's Freezer Meats, 438
F.3d 1337 (8th Cir. 1971); Solomon Valley Feedlot, 557 F.2d at 717;
Gerace v. Utica Veal Co., 580 F. Supp. 1465, 1470 (N.D.N.Y. 1984).
False weighing can occur in various ways. In some cases, the regulated
entity records inaccurate weights using an improperly calibrated scale.
In other cases, a regulated entity uses the scale improperly. Among
examples where packers have been found to have committed this deceptive
practice, in in re: DuQuoin Packing Company, Decatur Packing Division
and William S. Martin, 41 Agric. Dec. 1367 (1982), a weigher committed
a deceptive practice when he failed to properly adjust an otherwise
properly working scale to a zero balance prior to weighing, which
caused the scale to register less than actual weights. Weighing is ``a
serious matter and one of paramount importance to the farmer, industry
and consumers.'' In re Trenton Livestock, Inc., 33 Agric. Dec. 499, 510
aff'd 510 F.2d 966 (4th Cir. 1975). Even if a regulated entity does not
intentionally set out to deceive with respect to the weight of
livestock, the Act does not require proof of a particularized intent.
Parchman v. U.S. Dep't of Agric., 852 F.2d 858, 864 (6th Cir. 1988)
(interpreting sec. 312 of the Act). Short weighing alone is enough to
be an unfair and deceptive practice under the Act, without regard to
the competitive injury the short weighing causes. Garace, 580 F. Supp.
at 1470.
False or inaccurate grading has the same effect as false weighing
because deceptive grading prevents the seller from receiving the full
value of their livestock or poultry. USDA's Judicial Officer found a
deceptive practice when
[[Page 60034]]
a packer failed to inform hog producers of a change in the formula it
used to estimate lean percent in hogs. Lean percent was one factor used
in determining price when the packer purchased hogs on a carcass merit
basis. USDA determined that nearly twenty thousand lots of hogs were
purchased under the changed formula without notice to producers,
resulting in payment of $1.8 million less than they would have received
under the previous formula. In re: Excel Corporation, 63 Agric. Dec.
317 (2004), aff'd Excel Corp. v. United States Dep't of Agric., 397
F.3d 1285, 1293 (10th Cir. 2005). This type of deceptive practice harms
honest competitors because ``[h]ad hog producers been alerted to the
change, they could have shopped their hogs to other packers.'' 397 F.3d
at 1291.
Paying ``kickbacks'' and commercial bribery may occur both in the
contract formation and during the operation of a contract. Whether the
payment comes before or after the contract was formed, those payments
are a deceptive practice. For example, in Holiday Food Serv., Inc. v.
Dep't of Agric., 820 F.2d 1103, 1105 (9th Cir. 1987), a packer paid the
purchasing agents of hotels and restaurants ``kickbacks'' after they
purchased meats for their principals. And, in Nat'l Beef Packing Co. v.
Sec'y of Agric., 605 F.2d 1167, 1168 (10th Cir. 1979), not only was the
commercial bribery a violation of the Act, but the court also agreed
with the Secretary that a packer's executives had a positive duty to
inquire into the payment of commissions that served as bribes. Id.
Payment violations can be deceptive, especially issuance of
insufficient funds checks. E.g. In Re: Mid-W. Veal Distributors, d/b/a
Nagle Packing Co., & Milton Nagle, 43 Agric. Dec. 1124, 1140 (1984).
Failing to pay for meat has also been found to be deceptive in numerous
instances.\126\ Under the similar language of sec. 312 of the Act, the
Eighth Circuit explained that timely payment was unfair and deceptive
even prior to the enactment of sec. 409 of the Act: ``Timely payment in
a livestock purchase prevents the seller from being forced, in effect,
to finance the transaction.'' Van Wyk v. Bergland, 570 F.2d 701, 704
(8th Cir. 1978).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\126\ See, e.g. Milton Abeles, Inc. v. Creekstone Farms Premium
Beef, LLC, No. 06-CV-3893(JFB)(AKT), 2009 WL 875553, at *19
(E.D.N.Y. Mar. 30, 2009) (citing Liberty Mutual Ins. Co. v. Bankers
Trust Co., 758 F.Supp. 890, 896 n. 7 (S.D.N.Y.1991); In re FLA
Packing & Provision, Inc., and C. Elliot Kane, P & S Docket No. D-
95-0062, 1997 WL 809036, at *6 n. 1 (1997); In re: Central Packing
Co., Inc. d/b/a Plat-Central Food Services Co., Inc., a/k/a Plat-
Central Food Service Supply Co., and Albert Brust, an individual, 48
Agric. Dec. 290, 297-99 (1989)); see also In Re: Ampex Meats Corp. &
Laurence B. Greenburg., 47 Agric. Dec. 1123, 1125 (1988) (citing In
Re: Rotches Pork Packers, Inc. & David A. Rotches., 46 Agric. Dec.
573, 579-80 (U.S.D.A. Apr. 13, 1987) In Re: George Ash, 22 Agric.
Dec. 889 (1963); In re Goldring Packing Co., 21 Agric. Dec. 26
(1962); In Re: Eastern Meats, Inc., 21 Agric. Dec. 580 134 (1962)).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The live poultry dealer's honesty is vitally important to poultry
growers. Because much of the payment system relies on information that
is wholly within the live poultry dealer's control, deception is
particularly dangerous. The Department has received complaints
regarding statements made during the operation of the contract that led
producers to believe that specific terms would not be enforced, only to
see the live poultry dealer implement policy changes that led to
immediate changes to contracting requirements. These sorts of
communications may reach the level of unlawful deception under the P&S
Act, which reaches beyond common-law fraud. Likewise, for the market to
function, livestock producers must be able to reasonably rely on a
packer's calculation of value, and they must be able to rely on
statements and accountings the packers deliver.
D. Deceptive Practices in the Termination of Contract
Proposed Sec. 201.306(d) would prohibit regulated entities from
terminating a contractortaking any otheradverse action against a
covered producer by employing pretext, false or misleading statements,
or omission to state a material fact necessary to make the statement
not false or misleading.
AMS notes, for example, that poultry growers complain of companies
terminating their broiler production contracts based on pretext or for
a deceptive reason. Contract termination puts the grower at severe risk
of significant economic loss. A production broiler house often has
significant long-term financial obligations. The potential loss
includes not only the loss of production income, but construction is
often financed with mortgages on the grower's farm or family home.
Pretextual cancellation may make even the sale or transfer of the
broiler production house impossible because purchasers may be unable to
determine if the broiler houses have value.
E. Deceptive Practices in Refusal To Deal
Proposed Sec. 201.306(e) would prohibit the deceptive practice of
providing false or misleading information to a producer, grower, or
association of producers or growers concerning the regulated entity's
refusal to contract. AMS proposes this ban to meet producer concerns
that packers use pretext to deny access to certain livestock
transactions and pretextual refusals to renew growing contracts. This
proposal also supports the statutory prohibition in sec. 202(a) of the
Act of unjust discrimination and the sec. 202(b) prohibition of undue
preferences and prejudices. A refusal to contract may be lawful or
unlawful. So, while an ordinary refusal to deal is not a violation of
the Act, some refusals have unlawful purposes or effects. Group
boycott, for example, has unlawful purpose and effect. See Klor's, Inc.
v. Broadway-Hale Stores, Inc., 359 U.S. 207 (1959). Group boycott--or
blanket refusal to deal--forces the boycotted party to adopt conforming
trade practices, or they must quit the business entirely. Id. Under the
P&S Act, unlawful practices have included attempts to force livestock
markets to adopt terms that were favorable to the packer. See De Jong
Packing Co. v. U.S. Dep't of Agric., 618 F.2d 1329, 1336 (9th Cir.
1980). Packers may not ``exert a coercive influence upon the trade
practices of third parties in order to exact more favorable terms than
they could otherwise obtain.'' Id. Moreover, refusal to deal was firmly
on the minds of the legislature when the Act passed. 61 Cong. Rec. 1861
(1921) (explaining that packers refused to bid on a load of cattle in
more than one market, thereby preventing sellers from re-consigning
livestock to different markets). Deceptions related to these refusals
to deal may conceal other unlawful practices designed to pose barriers
to entry for farmers that may wish to enter these markets.
A regulated entity that refused to contract on unlawful grounds may
well choose to hide their motives with misleading or deceptive
statements. This proposed regulation would recognize misleading
statements in a refusal to enter into a contract as ``deceptive''
within the meaning of the Act.
F. Request for Comments on Proposed Sec. 201.306
AMS invites comment on (1) the proposed addition of new Sec.
201.306 to the regulations and (2) the specific proposed prohibitions
on deceptive practices. Parties who wish to comment anonymously may do
so by entering ``N/A'' in the fields that would identify the commenter.
While comments on any aspect of the proposed new section are welcome,
AMS specifically solicits comments on the following:
1. Do the proposed regulations accurately and adequately identify
recurrent deceptive practices in the livestock and poultry industries?
Please
[[Page 60035]]
explain why or why not and explain in detail any areas of deception
that may be missing.
2. Are there recurrent deceptive practices that are not adequately
addressed by these regulations? Please discuss.
3. Should deception in contract refusal be governed by the
categorical approach as proposed, or should it be governed by a single
statement setting out one standard for contract formation, performance,
and termination? Why or why not?
4. Should deception be structured instead around prohibiting the
deceptive pretext, statement, or omission, rather than prohibiting the
contractual activity based on the deceptive statement or omission? Why
or why not?
5. Do the prohibitions against ``employing'' certain false or
misleading statements, pretexts, and omissions in the formation,
operation, etc., of a contract appropriately capture the importance or
effect of the misleading statement (its materiality or relevance to the
producer or the formation/operation/etc., of the contract)? Or should a
regulated entity be prohibited from employing any pretext, false or
misleading statement, or omission of material facts necessary to make a
statement not false or misleading, in connection with making,
enforcing, or cancelling contact? In either case, if not, how could AMS
better approach this issue, including using elements or defenses?
6. Are there other elements, such as the reasonableness of the
recipient, that AMS should explicitly consider in a rule on deception?
Why or why not?
7. What specific challenges or burdens might regulated entities
face in complying with the deceptive practices provisions of the
proposed rule? How do they differ from existing policies, procedures,
and practices of regulated entities?
8. Should AMS propose specific recordkeeping provisions relating to
these deceptive practices? If so, what should they include?
9. Should AMS require that all contracts with respect to livestock,
meats, meat food products, livestock products in unmanufactured form,
or live poultry be in writing? Why or why not?
10. Do the provisions on deception provide sufficiently clarity
regarding deception with respect to a regulated entity's course of
business dealings generally or ordinarily offered? If not, how might
such a provision be structured?
11. Should a failure to continue to buy in the cash market,
following a regular or dependable pattern or practice of such buying,
be treated for the purposes of this proposed rule as more similar to
termination of a contract, rather than as refusal to deal? Why or why
not?
IV. Severability
AMS proposes to add a new Sec. 201.390 to 9 CFR part 201 of the
Packers and Stockyards regulations. This provision would ensure that if
any provision of part 201 was declared invalid, or if the applicability
of any of its provisions to any person or circumstances was held
invalid, the validity of the remaining provisions of part 201 or their
applicability to other persons or circumstances would not be affected.
Such a provision is typical in AMS regulations that may cover several
different topics and is proposed for addition here as a matter of
housekeeping.
V. Required Regulatory Analyses
Paperwork Reduction Act
In accordance with the Paperwork Reduction Act of 1995 (PRA) (44
U.S.C. Chapter 35), AMS has requested Office of Management and Budget
(OMB) approval of the information collection and recordkeeping
requirement of proposed Sec. 201.304(c). AMS invites comments on this
new information collection. All comments received on this information
collection will be summarized and included in the final request for OMB
approval. Below is detailed information on the burdens of these new
information collection and recordkeeping requirements. A similar amount
of detail can be found in the Regulatory Impact Analysis (RIA), as the
recordkeeping costs apply to both the PRA and the RIA. Comments on this
section will be considered in the final rule analysis.
OMB Number: 0581-NEW.
Expiration Date of Approval: This is a NEW collection.
Type of Request: Approval of a New Information Collection.
Abstract: This rulemaking has been determined to be significant for
the purposes of Executive Order (E.O.) 12866 and, therefore, has been
accordingly reviewed by the Office of Management and Budget. As a
required part of the regulatory process, AMS prepared an economic
analysis of the costs and benefits of the proposed Sec. Sec. 201.302,
201.304, 201.306, and 201.390.
In the late 1910s, Congress was concerned about the monopoly power
wielded by the five large meatpackers and the consequent constraint to
competition and diminished economic opportunities for rural
communities, agricultural producers and small food manufacturers.\127\
Congress believed the existing the Sherman Act and Federal Trade
Commission Act was inadequate in its protections of agricultural
producers.\128\ Consequently, Congress expanded and furthered its
protections of farmers and ranchers by enacting the 1921 Packers and
Stockyards Act and giving the Secretary of Agriculture authority to
regulate the meat packing industry.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\127\ See 61 Cong. Rec. 1860 (1921) (House Floor Debate).
\128\ See, Shively, J. and Roberts, J., ``Competition Under the
Packers and Stockyards Act: What Now?'' 15 Drake Journal of
Agricultural Law 419, 422-423 (2010); and Current Legislation, 22
Columbia Law Review 68, 69 (1922).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Proposed Sec. 201.304(a) ensures full and non-discriminatory
market access for producers who would be considered vulnerable to
prejudice, disadvantage, or exclusion from the marketplace. The
provision would also prohibit undue prejudices and disadvantages based
upon the status of the covered producer as a cooperative. Proposed
Sec. 201.304(b) would address retaliation by setting out protected
activities that a covered producer may engage in but that a regulated
entity may not use as grounds for unjust discrimination or undue
prejudice.
Proposed Sec. 201.304(c)(1) would require live poultry dealers,
swine contractors, and packers to incur recordkeeping costs by
requiring regulated entities to retain all relevant records relating to
their compliance with proposed Sec. 201.304(a) and (b) for no less
than 5 years. AMS is proposing this information collection and
recordkeeping requirement to assist in evaluating compliance with
proposed Sec. 201.304 and to facilitate investigations and
enforcements based on producer and grower complaints. Costs of
recordkeeping include maintaining and updating records by regulated
entities as will be discussed and quantified below.
Proposed Sec. 201.304(c)(2) lists records that may be relevant and
that must be retained if they exist. Specifically, regulated entities
would be required to retain records relating to policies and
procedures, staff training materials, materials informing covered
producers regarding reporting mechanisms and protections, compliance
testing, board of directors' oversight materials, and the number and
nature of complaints received relevant to proposed Sec. 201.304.
The information collection and recordkeeping requirement in this
[[Page 60036]]
request may be valuable in reducing instances of undue prejudices,
discrimination, and retaliation in the livestock and poultry
industries, in accordance with the purposes of the P&S Act, 1921. The
information collection request and recordkeeping requirement may also
bolster AMS's ability to review the records of regulated entities
during compliance reviews and investigations based on complaints of
undue prejudices, discrimination, and retaliation in the livestock and
poultry industries.
Live Poultry Dealer, Swine Contractor, and Packer Recordkeeping Costs
Estimate of Burden: Public reporting burden for maintaining records
for this information collection is estimated to average 4.25 hours per
response in the first year, and 3.50 hours thereafter.
Respondents: Live poultry dealers, swine contractors, and packers
Estimated Number of Respondents: 1,026
Estimated Total Annual Burden on Respondents: 4,361 hours in the
first year and 3,591 hours thereafter.
Comments: Comments are invited on: (1) Whether the proposed
collection of the information is necessary for the proper performance
of the functions of the agency, including whether the information will
have practical utility; (2) the accuracy of the agency's estimate of
the burden of the proposed collection of information; (3) ways to
enhance the quality, utility, and clarity of the information to be
collected; and (4) ways to minimize the burden of the collection of
information on those who are to respond; including through the use of
appropriate automated, electronic, mechanical, or other technological
collection techniques or other forms of information technology.
Information Collection and Recordkeeping Costs of Proposed Sec.
201.304(c)
Costs to comply with the proposed recordkeeping are likely
relatively low. Proposed Sec. 201.304(c), requires certain specific
records that, if the regulated entity maintains, should be kept for a
period of five years, including policies and procedures, staff training
materials, materials informing covered producers regarding reporting
mechanisms and protections, compliance testing, board of directors'
oversight materials, and the number and nature of unduly prejudicial or
discrimination-based complaints received relevant to proposed Sec.
201.304(a) and (b).
Costs of recordkeeping include regulated entities maintaining and
updating compliance records. From the perspective of the regulated
entity, recordkeeping is a direct cost. Some smaller regulated entities
that currently don't maintain records, may voluntarily decide to
develop formal policies, procedures, training, etc., to comply with the
rulemaking and would then have records to maintain.
AMS expects the recordkeeping costs would be comprised of the time
required by regulated entities to store and maintain records. AMS
expects that the costs will be relatively small because some packers,
live poultry dealers, and swine contractors may currently have few
records concerning policies and procedures, staff training materials,
materials informing covered producers regarding reporting mechanisms
and protections, compliance testing, board of directors' oversight
materials, and the number and nature of complaints received related to
prejudicial and discriminatory treatment. Some firms might not have any
records to store. Others already store the records and may have no new
costs.
The amount of time required to keep records were estimated by AMS
subject matter experts. These experts were economists and supervisors
with many years of experience in AMS's PSD conducting investigations
and compliance reviews of regulated entities. AMS used the May 2020
U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) Occupational Employment and Wage
Statistics for the time values in this analysis.\129\ BLS estimated an
average hourly wage for general and operations managers in animal
slaughtering and processing to be $65.84. The average hourly wage for
lawyers in food manufacturing was $80.39. In applying the cost
estimates, AMS marked-up the wages by 41.56 percent to account for
fringe benefits.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\129\ Estimates are available at U.S. Bureau of Labor
Statistics. Occupational Employment and Wage Statistics, available
at https://www.bls.gov/oes/special.requests/oesm20all.zip (accessed
8/9/2022).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
AMS expects that recordkeeping costs would be correlated with the
size of the firms. AMS ranked packers, live poultry dealers, and swine
contractors by size and grouped them into quartiles, estimating more
recordkeeping time for the largest entities in the first quartile than
for the smallest entities in the fourth quartile. The first quartile
contains the largest 25 percent of entities, and the fourth quartile
contains the smallest 25 percent of entities. AMS estimated that
proposed Sec. 201.304(c) would require an average of 4.00 hours of
administrative assistant time, 1.50 hours of time each from managers,
attorneys, and information technology staff for packers, live poultry
dealers, and swine contractors in the first quartile to setup and
maintain the required records in the first year. AMS expects the
packers, live poultry dealers, and swine contractors in the second
quartile would require an average of 2.00 hours of administrative
assistant time, 0.75 hours of time each from managers, attorneys, and
information technology staff for first year costs. The third quartile
would require 1.33 hours of administrative assistant time, 0.50 hours
of time each from managers, attorneys, and information technology staff
for first year costs, and the fourth quartile would require 0.67 hours
of administrative assistant time, 0.25 hours of time each from
managers, attorneys, and information technology staff.
AMS also expects that packers, live poultry dealers, and swine
contractors will incur continuing recordkeeping costs in each
successive year. AMS estimated that proposed Sec. 201.304(c) would
require an average of 3.00 hours of administrative assistant time, 1.50
hours of time each from managers, attorneys, and 1.00 hour of time from
information technology staff for packers, live poultry dealers, and
swine contractors in the largest quartile to setup and maintain the
required records in each succeeding year. AMS expects that packers,
live poultry dealers, and swine contractors in the second quartile
would require an average of 1.50 hours of administrative assistant
time, 0.75 hours of time each from managers, attorneys, and 0.50 hours
of time from information technology staff in each succeeding year. The
third quartile would require 1.00 hour of administrative assistant
time, 0.50 hours of time each from managers, attorneys, and 0.33 hours
of time from information technology staff in each succeeding year, and
the smallest quartile would require 0.50 hours of administrative
assistant time, 0.25 hours of time each from managers, and attorneys,
and 0.17 hours from information technology staff.
Estimated first-year costs for recordkeeping requirements in
proposed Sec. 201.304(c) totaled $26,000 for live poultry
dealers,\130\ $170,000 for swine contractors,\131\ and $107,000 for
[[Page 60037]]
packers.\132\ Estimated yearly continuing costs for recordkeeping
requirements in Sec. 201.304(c) totaled $23,000 for live poultry
dealers,\133\ $147,000 for swine contractors,\134\ and $93,000 for
packers.\135\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\130\ 89 live poultry dealers x ($39.69 per hour admin. cost x
(4 hours + 2 hours + 1.33 hours + .67 hours)) + ($93.20 per hour
manger cost x (1.5 hours + .75 hours + .5 hours + .25 hours)) +
($113.80 legal cost x (1.5 hours + .75 hours + .5 hours + .25
hours)) + ($82.50 information tech cost x (1.5 hours + .75 hours +
.5 hours + .25 hours))/4 = $26,390.
\131\ 575 swine contractors x ($39.69 per hour admin. cost x(4
hours + 2 hours + 1.33 hours + .67 hours)) + ($93.20 per hour manger
cost x (1.5 hours + .75 hours + .5 hours + .25 hours)) + (113.80
legal cost x(1.5 hours + .75 hours + .5 hours + .25 hours)) +
($82.50 information tech cost x (1.5 hours + .75 hours + .5 hours +
.25 hours))/4 = $170,496.
\132\ 362 packers x ($39.69 per hour admin. cost x (4 hours + 2
hours + 1.33 hours + .67 hours)) + ($93.20 per hour manger cost x
(1.5 hours + .75 hours + .5 hours + .25 hours)) + ($113.80 legal
cost x (1.5 hours + .75 hours + .5 hours + .25 hours)) + ($82.50
information tech cost x (1.5 hours + .75 hours + .5 hours + .25
hours))/4 = $107,338.
\133\ 89 live poultry dealers x($39.69 per hour admin. cost x (4
hours + 2 hours + 1.33 hours + .67 hours)) + ($93.20 per hour manger
cost x (1.5 hours + .75 hours + .5 hours + .25 hours)) + ($113.80
legal cost x (1.5 hours + .75 hours + .5 hours + .25 hours)) +
$82.50 information tech cost x (1.5 hours + .75 hours + .5 hours +
.25 hours))/4 = $22,788.
\134\ 575 swine contractors x ($39.69 per hour admin. cost x (4
hours + 2 hours + 1.33 hours + .67 hours)) + ($93.20 per hour manger
cost x (1.5 hours + .75 hours + .5 hours + .25 hours)) + ($113.80
legal cost x (1.5 hours + .75 hours + .5 hours + .25 hours)) +
$82.50 information tech cost x (1.5 hours + .75 hours + .5 hours +
.25 hours))/4 = $147,225.
\135\ 362 packers x ($39.69 per hour admin. cost x (4 hours + 2
hours + 1.33 hours + .67 hours)) + ($93.20 per hour manger cost x
(1.5 hours + .75 hours + .5 hours + .25 hours)) + ($113.80 legal
cost x (1.5 hours + .75 hours + .5 hours + .25 hours)) + ($82.50
information tech cost x (1.5 hours + .75 hours + .5 hours + .25
hours))/4 = $92,688.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Breaking out costs by market, AMS expects recordkeeping
requirements in proposed Sec. 201.304(c) to cost beef packers $47,000
in the first year and $41,000 in each following year. Proposed Sec.
201.304(c) would cost lamb packers $21,000 in the first year and
$18,000 in successive years. Proposed Sec. 201.304(c) would cost pork
packers $39,000, and it would cost swine contractors $170,000 for a
total of $209,000 in the first year. Proposed Sec. 201.304(c) would
cost swine contractors $147,000 in successive years, and it would cost
pork packers $33,000 for a total $180,000.
Executive Order 12866 and the Regulatory Flexibility Act
This rulemaking has been determined to be significant for the
purposes of E.O. 12866 and, therefore, has accordingly reviewed by the
Office of Management and Budget. As a required part of the regulatory
process, AMS prepared an economic analysis of the costs and benefits of
the proposed Sec. Sec. 201.302, 201.304, 201.306, and 201.390. This
regulatory filing is comprised of definitions in Sec. 201.302,
specific prohibited discriminatory and unduly prejudicial practices in
Sec. 201.304, specific prohibited deceptive practices in Sec.
201.306, and a statement of severability among the provisions in Sec.
201.390. The definitions in Sec. 201.302 of a covered producer, market
vulnerable individual, livestock producer, and regulated entity would
apply to proposed Sec. Sec. 201.304 and 201.306, and the regulatory
impacts of the definitions are captured in the regulatory impacts of
Sec. Sec. 201.304 and 201.306, which are highlighted in this analysis.
The statement of severability in proposed Sec. 201.390 has no
quantified regulatory impact, as it only serves to ensure that if any
provision of Sec. 201.302, Sec. 201.304, or Sec. 201.306 is declared
invalid or the applicability to any person or circumstance is invalid,
the remainder of the provisions would remain valid.
Proposed Sec. 201.304 would provide notice to the industry
regarding unduly prejudicial and discriminatory practices that are
prohibited and if they occur would be a violation of sec. 202(a) of the
P&S Act. Practices that would be prohibited as unduly prejudicial and
discriminatory under proposed Sec. 201.304(a) include prejudice,
disadvantage, or discrimination that otherwise inhibits market access
to a covered producer with respect to livestock, poultry, meats, and
meat food products based on a covered producer's status as a market
vulnerable individual or as a cooperative. Examples of prejudice or
disadvantage are included in proposed Sec. 201.304(a)(3) and include
offering less favorable contract terms than those generally offered,
refusing to deal, or adversely differential performance, enforcement,
or termination of contracts.
Proposed Sec. 201.304(b)(1) prohibits retaliation or otherwise
taking an adverse action against a covered producer because of the
covered producer's participation in certain activities described in
Sec. 201.304(b)(2). Proposed Sec. 201.304(b)(2)(i)-(vi) list
activities that are protected under Sec. 201.304(b)(1). A covered
producer that communicates with a government agency, or petitions a
court, legislature, or government agency for redress of grievances is
protected from retaliation with respect to livestock, meats, meat food
products, livestock products in unmanufactured form, or live poultry. A
covered producer who asserts rights granted under the P&S Act, contract
rights, or rights to form or join a producer or grower association to
collectively market livestock or poultry would also be protected from
retaliation. Additionally, covered producers would be protected from
retaliation if they communicate or cooperate with a person for purposes
of improving production or marketing of livestock or poultry, negotiate
with a regulated entity for purposes of exploring a business
relationship, or support or participate as a witness in any proceeding
under the P&S Act or a proceeding that relates to an alleged violation
of law by a regulated entity.
Proposed Sec. 201.306(a) would provide notice to the industry
regarding specific deceptive practices in which a regulated entity may
not engage with respect to livestock, meats, meat food products,
livestock products in unmanufactured form, or live poultry. Proposed
Sec. 201.306(b)-(e) would prohibit deceptive practices in contract
formation, contract performance, contract termination, and contract
refusal with respect to livestock and meats and lists specific
practices that would constitute a violation of sec. 202(a) of the P&S
Act. The prohibited deceptive practices include making or modifying a
contract, performing under or enforcing a contract, terminating a
contract, or refusing to contract with a covered producer based on
pretext, omission of material facts, or false or misleading statements.
Proposed Sec. 201.390 would ensure that if any provision of Sec.
201.302, Sec. 201.304, or Sec. 201.306 is declared invalid or the
applicability to any person or circumstance is invalid, the remainder
of the provision would remain valid.
Protecting rights in contracting is an important feature of both
proposed Sec. Sec. 201.304 and 201.306. Proposed Sec. 201.304
prohibits retaliation by regulated entities through termination of
contracts, non-renewal of contracts, refusing to deal, and interference
in farm real estate contracts as unduly prejudicial and discriminatory
practices. Proposed Sec. 201.306 prohibits deceptive practices by
regulated entities in contracting with covered producers including
making or modifying a contract, performing under or enforcing a
contract, terminating a contract, or refusing to contract with a
covered producer based on pretext, false or misleading statements, or
omission of material facts. A discussion of contracting in these
industries is, therefore, useful in explaining the need for these
additional regulations. As will be seen in the next three tables below
defining market shares of regulated entities and the discussion that
follows, the unduly prejudicial, discriminatory, and deceptive
practices, including retaliation, that proposed Sec. Sec. 201.304 and
201.306 would prohibit are partially attributable to the structure of
the livestock and poultry industries, the imbalance of market power
between
[[Page 60038]]
regulated entities, producers, growers, and the potential market
failure of asymmetrical information, which, along with imperfect
competition, contributes to hold-up.
Prevalence of Contracting in Cattle, Hog, and Poultry Industries
Growing, production, and marketing contracts feature prominently in
the livestock and poultry industries. As outlined above, several
provisions in proposed Sec. Sec. 201.304 and 201.306 would affect the
process of making, enforcing, and terminating contracts for livestock,
poultry, and meat grown or marketed under contract.
The type of contracting varies among cattle, hogs, and poultry.
Broilers, the largest segment of poultry, are almost exclusively grown
under production contracts, in which the live poultry dealers, a
regulated entity, own the birds and provide poultry growers with feed
and medication to raise and care for the birds until they reach the
desired market size. Poultry growers provide the housing, the skill and
efforts of labor, water, electricity, fuel, and provide for waste
removal. Fed cattle marketing contracts typically take the form of
marketing agreements as discussed below. Hog production falls between
these two extremes.
As shown in the table below, over 96 percent of all broilers and
over 42 percent of all hogs are grown under contractual arrangements.
Similar to poultry contracts, swine contractors typically own the
slaughter hogs and sell the finished hogs to pork packers. The swine
contractors typically provide feed and medication to the swine
production contract growers who own the growing facilities and provide
growing services. The following table shows that the percentage of
contract growing arrangements by species has remained relatively stable
between 2007 and 2017.
Table 4--Percentage of Poultry and Hog Raised and Delivered Under Production Contracts \136\
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Species 2007 2012 2017
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Broilers........................................................ 96.5 96.4 96.3
Turkeys......................................................... 67.7 68.5 69.5
Hogs............................................................ 43.3 43.5 42.4
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Other types of contracts include marketing agreements and forward
contracts. Under marketing agreements, livestock producers market their
livestock to a packer for slaughter under a verbal or written
agreement. Under forward contracts, producers and packers agree to
terms on a future sale and purchase of livestock. These types of
agreements and contracts are commonly referred to as Alternative
Marketing Arrangements (AMAs). Pricing mechanisms vary across AMAs.
Some AMAs rely on a reported spot, or negotiated, market price or
exchange-based futures price for at least one aspect of its price,
while others involve complicated pricing formulas with premiums and
discounts based on carcass merits. The livestock producer and packer
agree on a pricing mechanism under AMAs, but usually not on a specific
price.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\136\ Agricultural Census, 2012 and 2017, available at https://www.nass.usda.gov/Publications/AgCensus/2017/Full_Report/Volume_1,_Chapter_1_US/usv1.pdf (last accessed 8/9/2022).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
AMS reports the number of cattle sold to packers under formula,
forward contract, and negotiated pricing mechanisms. The following
table illustrates the prevalence of contracting in the marketing of fed
cattle. Formula pricing methods and forward contracts are two forms of
AMA contracts. Thus, the first two columns in the following table are
cattle marketed under contract and the third column represents the spot
market, or negotiated market, for fed cattle including negotiated grid.
The data in the below table show that the AMA contracting of cattle has
increased since 2010. Approximately 55 percent of fed cattle were
marketed under contracts in 2010. By 2021, the percentage of fed cattle
marketed to packers under AMA contracts had increased to just over 72
percent. These data also show the declines in the percentage of cattle
sold on the spot market from 45.6 in 2010 to 27.6 in 2021.
Table 5--Percentage of Fed Cattle Sold by Type of Purchase \137\
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Forward
Year Formula contract Negotiated
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
2010............................................................ 44.9 9.5 45.6
2011............................................................ 48.4 10.9 40.7
2012............................................................ 54.7 11.4 33.8
2013............................................................ 60.0 10.2 29.8
2014............................................................ 58.1 14.2 27.6
2015............................................................ 58.2 16.5 25.3
2016............................................................ 58.2 12.0 29.8
2017............................................................ 58.7 11.4 29.9
2018............................................................ 62.0 8.8 29.2
2019............................................................ 65.7 9.8 24.4
2020............................................................ 64.1 9.0 27.0
2021............................................................ 61.5 10.9 27.6
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
As previously discussed, and illustrated in Table 4 above, over 40
percent of hogs are grown under production contracts. These hogs are
then sold by swine contractors or to other contract production growers
to packers under marketing contracts.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\137\ U.S. Department of Agriculture, Agricultural Marketing
Service, available at: https://mpr.datamart.ams.usda.gov/
menu.do?path=Products\Cattle\Weekly%20Cattle (last accessed Aug.
2022).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
[[Page 60039]]
As can be seen in the below table, the percentage of hogs sold
under marketing contracts has increased since 2010 to over 98 percent
in 2020. The spot market for hogs has declined from 5.2 percent in 2010
to 1.5 percent in 2020. As these data demonstrate, almost all hogs are
marketed to packers under some type of marketing contract.
Table 6--Percentage of Hogs Sold by Type of Purchase \138\
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Other
marketing
Year arrangements Formula \140\ Negotiated
\139\
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
2010............................................................ 45.4 49.4 5.2
2011............................................................ 47.6 48.2 4.2
2012............................................................ 47.7 48.6 3.6
2013............................................................ 48.3 48.4 3.2
2014............................................................ 45.9 51.4 2.7
2015............................................................ 46.0 51.4 2.6
2016............................................................ 50.0 47.6 2.5
2017............................................................ 52.5 45.0 2.5
2018............................................................ 56.5 41.3 2.2
2019............................................................ 59.8 38.4 1.8
2020............................................................ 61.3 37.1 1.5
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Structural Issues in the Cattle, Hog, and Poultry Industries
The livestock and poultry industries are characterized by a high
volume of growing, production, and marketing contracts. High volume of
this type of contracting, coupled with high levels of market
concentration, may increase the risk for anticompetitive behaviors of
undue prejudice and discrimination, retaliation, and deception by
regulated entities, which can harm market vulnerable producers.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\138\ U.S. Department of Agriculture, Agricultural Marketing
Service, available at: https://mpr.datamart.ams.usda.gov/
menu.do?path=\Products (last accessed Aug. 2022).
\139\ Includes Packer Owned and Packer Sold, and Other Purchase
Arrangements.
\140\ Includes Swine Pork Market Formula, and Other Market
Formula.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Despite various policy and public concerns with contracting,
growing, production, and marketing contracts can offer certain benefits
to the contracting parties. Properly tailored, benefits can include
helping farmers, livestock producers, and processors manage price and
production risks, elicit the production of products with specific
quality attributes by tying prices to those attributes, and facilitate
the smooth flow of commodities to processing plants. Such attributes
may encourage certain efficiencies in use of farm and processing
capacities. Quality-related attributes and standards can incentivize
farmers to deliver products that consumers desire and produce products
in ways that reduce processing costs.\141\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\141\ RTI International, 2007, GIPSA Livestock and Meat
Marketing Study, Prepared for USDA, GIPSA; Stephen R. Koontz,
``Another Look at Alternative Marketing Arrangement Use by the
Cattle and Beef Industry,'' in Bart Fischer et al., ``The U.S. Beef
Supply Chain: Issues and Challenges Proceedings of a Workshop on
Cattle Markets,'' 2021. But see C. Robert Taylor, ``Market Structure
of the Livestock Industry,'' Testimony before the House Committee of
Agriculture, April 16, 2007, available at https://www.iatp.org/documents/c-robert-taylor-testimony-market-structure-of-the-livestock-industry; C. Robert Taylor, ``Harvested Cattle,
Slaughtered Markets,'' April 27, 2022, available at https://www.antitrustinstitute.org/work-product/aai-advisor-robert-taylor-issues-new-analysis-on-the-market-power-problem-in-beef-lays-out-new-policy-framework-for-ensuring-competition-and-fairness-in-cattle-and-beef-markets/(contesting quality incentives delivered
through these agreements).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
There are, however, trade-offs with the use of these contracts. In
concentrated industries, like the cattle, hog, and poultry industries,
where market power is present, these types of contracts may result in
increased opportunities for undue prejudices and discrimination,
retaliation, and deception, among other concerns, which cause
inefficiencies in the markets for livestock, poultry, and meat.\142\
Heightened market concentration implies that livestock producers and
poultry growers face fewer marketing and contract options compared to
less concentrated markets. Livestock producers and poultry growers may
find themselves in a take-it-or-leave it situation when a new or
renewal contract is presented due to a limited number of packers and
live poultry dealers with which to contract. Thus, livestock producers
and poultry dealers entering into new or renewal contracts may be taken
advantage of through discriminatory, deceptive, or retaliatory
practices.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\142\ Nathan H. Miller, et al., ``Buyer Power in the Beef
Packing Industry: An Update on Research in Progress,'' April 13,
2022, available at https://www.nathanhmiller.org/cattlemarkets.pdf.
See also Michael Kades, ``Protecting Livestock Producers and Chicken
Growers,'' Washington Center for Equitable Growth (May 5, 2022),
available at https://equitablegrowth.org/research-paper/protecting-livestock-producers-and-chicken-growers/.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Livestock and poultry contracts may hold producers and growers
captive, due to limited number of packers and live poultry dealers and
therefore susceptible to unjust, prejudicial and retaliatory practices.
For example, a contract that limits a poultry grower's services to a
single integrator, even if the contract provides for fair compensation
to the grower, still leaves the grower subject to retaliation risks.
The grower may face the hold-up risk that the contractor may require
additional capital investments or may face retaliation, when the
contractor imposes lower returns at the time of contract renewal.\143\
Some growers make substantial long-term capital investments as part of
livestock or poultry production contracts, including land, poultry or
hog houses, and equipment. Those investments may tie the grower to a
single contractor or integrator, furthering the indebtedness, and thus
also imbalance of power.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\143\ See Vukina and Leegomonchai, ``Oligopsony Power, Asset
Specificity, and Hold-Up: Evidence From The Broiler Industry,''
American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 88(3): 589-605 (August
2006).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
In the poultry industry, limited integrator choice may accentuate
contract risks. The data in Table 3 above show that 52 percent of
broiler growers, accounting for 56 percent of total production, report
having only one or two integrators in their local areas. Even where
multiple growers are present, there are high costs to switching, owing
to the differences in technical specifications that integrators
require. The growers likely need to invest in new equipment and learn
to apply different operational techniques due to different breeds,
target weights and grow-out cycles.
[[Page 60040]]
In 2013, production contracts covered $58 billion in agricultural
production, 83 percent of which was poultry and hog contracts.\144\
Most hogs are produced and marketed under production and marketing
contracts. Open market negotiated trade represented 9 percent of total
trades for hogs in 2008 and dropped to 2 percent in 2020.\145\ In
effect, the only production/marketing choice for a hog producer is to
enter a contract.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\144\ MacDonald, J.M. ``Trends in Agricultural Contracts.''
Choices. 2015. Quarter 3. Available at https://www.choicesmagazine.org/choices-magazine/theme-articles/current-issues-in-agricultural-contracts/trends-in-agricultural-contracts,
accessed 9-19-22.
\145\ USDA, AMS, FTPP, Packers and Stockyards Division. Packer
Annual Reports, 2021 and 2012. Available at https://www.ams.usda.gov/reports/psd-annual-reports, accessed 9-19-22.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
In the cattle sector, cow-calf operations incur a significant
investment in breeding stock and typically sell steers and heifers once
a year. Price risk can therefore rise from the months-long production
process.\146\ Access to competitive markets, absent from
discrimination, undue prejudice, and retaliation, is important to the
economic livelihood of vulnerable producers. Reduced marketing
options--fewer options to sell on the spot market, or lack of access to
contracts--can leave producers susceptible to unfair trade practices.
Spot market trades, or negotiated trades, as opposed to marketing
agreements or contracts, for fed cattle accounted for 51 percent of all
trades in 2008 and fell to 27 percent in 2020.\147\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\146\ Martinez, C.C., Maples, J.G. and Benavidez, J. Beef Cattle
Markets and COVID-19. Applied Economics Perspectives and Policy,
(2021) 43: 304-314. Available at https://doi.org/10.1002/aepp.13080,
accessed 9/19/22.
\147\ USDA, AMS, FTPP, Packers and Stockyards Division. Packer
Annual Reports, 2021 and 2012. Available at https://www.ams.usda.gov/reports/psd-annual-reports, accessed 9-19-22.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
A 2006 survey indicated that growers with access to a single
integrator received 7 to 8 percent less compensation, on average, than
farmers located in areas with 4 or more integrators.\148\ If live
poultry dealers already possess some market power to reduce prices for
poultry growing services, some contracts can extend that power by
raising the costs of entry for new competitors or allowing for price
discrimination.\149\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\148\ MacDonald, J. and N. Key. ``Market Power in Poultry
Production Contracting? Evidence from a Farm Survey.'' Journal of
Agricultural and Applied Economics. 44(4) (November 2012): 477-490.
\149\ See, e.g., Williamson, Oliver E. ``Markets and
Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications,'' New York: The
Free Press (1975); Edlin, Aaron S. & Stefan Reichelstein (1996)
``Holdups, Standard Breach Remedies, and Optimal Investment,'' The
American Economic Review 86(3): 478- 501 (June 1996).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
One indication of potential market power is industry
concentration.\150\ Table 2 presented earlier, shows the level of
concentration in the livestock and poultry slaughtering industries for
2010-2020. The table shows the combined market share of the four
largest steer and heifer slaughterers remained stable between 83 and 85
percent from 2010 to 2019 and dropped to 81 percent in 2020. Four-firm
concentration ratios for hog and broiler slaughter has also remained
relatively stable between 62 and 70 percent and 51 and 54 percent,
respectively.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\150\ For additional discussion see MacDonald, J.M. 2016
``Concentration, contracting, and competition policy in U.S.
agribusiness,'' Competition Law Review, No. 1-2016: 3-8.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
As discussed previously, the data in Table 2 are estimates of
national four-firm concentration ratios at the national level, but the
relevant economic markets for livestock and poultry may be regional or
local, and concentration in the relevant market may be higher than the
national level. For example, while poultry markets may appear to be the
least concentrated in terms of the four-firm concentration ratios
presented above, relevant economic markets for poultry growing services
are more localized than markets for fed cattle or hogs, and local
concentration in poultry markets is often greater than in hog and other
livestock markets. The data presented earlier in Table 3 highlights
this issue by showing the limited ability a poultry grower has to
switch to a different integrator. As a result, national concentration
may not demonstrate accurately the options poultry growers in a
particular region face.
The levels of industry concentration shown in Tables 2 and 3 may
contribute to oligopolistic market power and asymmetric information.
The result is that the contracts bargained between the parties may
leave livestock producers, swine production contract growers, and
poultry growers vulnerable to detrimental risks of anticompetitive
conduct such as prejudice and discrimination, retaliation, and
deception due to the structural issues discussed above and may result
in inefficiencies in the marketplace.
Asymmetric Information
There is asymmetry in the information available to livestock
producers and livestock and poultry growers and the packers, swine
contractors, and live poultry dealers with whom they contract. The
larger packers, swine contractors, and live poultry dealers generally
have more information (costs of production, input quality, and consumer
demand, for example) that is useful in contracting than the smaller
livestock producers and livestock and poultry growers. This asymmetry
of information can lead to deceptive practices by regulated entities
with superior information in making or modifying production, marketing,
or growing contracts, performing under, enforcing, or terminating these
contracts, or refusing to contract with a covered producer based on
pretext, omission of information, or false or misleading statements.
Some marketing contracts for fed cattle, for example, use various
plant averages in the calculation for the base price of the cattle in
the marketing contract. Only the packer has the information about the
plant averages and producers cannot independently verify the
information. Similar issues exist in hog marketing contracts. For
contracts based on the pork cutout, the hog packer has more information
about the direct retail pork demand and hence pork cutout prices than
hog sellers.
Asymmetric information is particularly acute in all contracts
between poultry growers and live poultry dealers. Live poultry dealers
hold information on how individual poultry growers perform under a
variety of contracts. The average number of contracts for the live
poultry dealers filing annual reports with AMS in 2020 was 251. The
largest live poultry dealers contracted with several thousand
growers.\151\ Most growers producing poultry under production contracts
are paid under a poultry grower ranking or ``tournament'' pay system.
Under tournament systems, the contract between the poultry grower and
the company for whom the grower raises poultry for slaughter pays the
grower based on a grouping, ranking, or comparison of poultry growers
delivering poultry to the same company during a specified period.
Generally, live poultry dealers provide most of the inputs to all the
growers in each poultry tournament used to determine grower pay. In
these tournaments, the live poultry dealers have information about the
quality of the inputs, while each grower only knows what he or she can
observe. Due to a lack of scales and tools to evaluate feed quality, a
grower may not be able to weigh, measure or evaluate the inputs it
received such as chicks and feed, and he or she almost
[[Page 60041]]
certainly will not know about the inputs received by other growers.
Live poultry dealers also have historical information concerning
growers' production and income under many different circumstances for
all the growers with which it contracts, while an individual grower,
like most other producers, only has information concerning his or her
own production and income. Prohibiting deception may serve to reduce
the negative impacts from asymmetric information. Prohibiting
retaliation against producers or growers because they joined a
cooperative or association, shared information to improve their
production or growing practices, or communicated with the government
should lead to reducing the information asymmetry between regulated
entities and producers and growers.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\151\ All live poultry dealers are required to annually file PSD
form 3002 ``Annual Report of Live Poultry Dealers,'' OMB control
number 0581-0308. The annual report form is available to public on
the internet at https://www.ams.usda.gov/sites/default/files/media/PSP3002.pdf.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Hold-Up Risk
Hold-up is another risk that is particularly acute in the service
contracts between poultry growers and live poultry dealers. Hold-up is
far less of a risk for hog and cattle producers, so the discussion here
is limited to poultry growing to highlight this risk to poultry
growers. Substantial gaps exist between the periods of time covered by
the contract and the mortgage on poultry housing, creating uncertainty
around whether growers will be able to repay their debt and recoup
their investments, introducing hold-up risk into the contracting
process. As discussed in the preamble, hold-up is the risk growers face
at the time of contract renewal when integrators make contract renewal
dependent on further grower investments not disclosed at the time of
the original agreements.\152\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\152\ Vukina, Tom, and Porametr Leegomonchai. ``Oligopsony
Power, Asset Specificity, and Hold-Up: Evidence from the Broiler
Industry.'' American Journal of Agricultural Economics 88 (2006).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
This is of concern in poultry production contracts because the
capital requirements related to growing chickens are significant and
highly specialized (that is, they have little value outside of growing
chickens). As a result, growers entering the market are tied to growing
chickens to pay off the financing of the capital investment. Growers
have reported that they must accept unfavorable contract terms or
endure unfavorable treatment during a contract--including inappropriate
limits on their ability to form associations, assert their rights under
the law or contract (such as viewing the weighing of broilers),
communicate with government entities, and seek alternative business
relationships--because they are tied to production to pay off lenders
and they have few, if any, alternative integrators with whom they can
contract. Hog producers which invest heavily in production facilities
face may similar risks.
Long term, this behavior may result in underinvestment in
production, which is inefficient. Alternatively, if growers do not
anticipate hold-up, then growers may spend too much on investments
because the integrator who demands them is not incurring any cost. The
resulting over-investment in capital by those growers facing hold-up is
also inefficient. Hold-up risk is a manifestation of both market power
and asymmetric information.
Hold-up risk can be alleviated with a prohibition on retaliation
for certain protected activities that enhance the competitive
environment and market integrity, as well as a prohibition on deception
and the accompanying reduction in asymmetric information. Increased
information to growers by allowing growers to freely communicate and
share information without fear of retaliation would allow growers to be
make more informed decision about the efficient level of capital in
which to invest.
Contracting, Industry Structure, and Market Failure: Summary of the
Need for Regulation
Growing, production, and marketing contracts benefit the livestock
and poultry industries. Existing structural issues may result in
imperfect competition, risks of undue prejudice and discrimination,
retaliation, deception, unequal bargaining power, and information
asymmetries, potentially increasing hold-up risk.
USDA's long-standing policy has been that the P&S Act prohibits the
type of conduct that this proposed rule addresses.\153\ Sections
201.304 and 201.306 will serve to fill-in gaps where other Federal and
state statutes, not specific to the agricultural sector, overlap and
fail to provide full protections. Proposed Sec. 201.304 would prohibit
packers, swine contractors, and live poultry dealers from unduly
discriminating and employing undue prejudices against market vulnerable
producers and cooperatives.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\153\ Agricultural Marketing Service, USDA, ``Undue and
Unreasonable Preferences and Advantages Under the Packers and
Stockyards Act,'' Final Rule, December 11, 2020, 85 FR 79779, 79787,
available at https://www.federalregister.gov/documents/2020/12/11/2020-27117/undue-and-unreasonable-preferences-and-advantages-under-the-packers-and-stockyards-act; Agricultural Marketing Service,
USDA, ``Frequently Asked Questions on the Enforcement of Undue and
Unreasonable Preferences under the Packers and Stockyards Act,''
August 2021, available at https://www.ams.usda.gov/rules-regulations/packers-and-stockyards-act/faq (last accessed Aug.
2022).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Proposed Sec. 201.304 would also prohibit retaliation including
termination of contracts, refusing to deal, refusing to renew a
contract, and interference in farm real estate transactions or
contracts with third parties. Retaliation would only be effective if
producers and growers had a small number of packers and live poultry
dealers to market their livestock or growing services. If producers and
growers had lots of choices among packers and live poultry dealers,
producers and growers would simply market their livestock or growing
services to a different packer or live poultry dealer if they were
being retaliated against. Thus, retaliation is more likely to occur in
markets with imperfect competition and an oligopsonistic structure,
such as the cattle, hog, and poultry markets. This clear statement
regarding prohibitions on retaliation could reduce instances of
retaliation against livestock producers and livestock and poultry
growers.
Proposed Sec. 201.304 would also protect various activities that
would allow covered producers to freely communicate with each other and
governmental entities. To establish a climate of compliance, regulated
entities would be required to maintain all relevant records in
compliance with proposed Sec. 201.304.
Proposed Sec. 201.306 would prohibit packers, swine contractors,
and live poultry dealers from employing deceptive practices against
producers and growers in forming, performing, and terminating contracts
and refusing to contract based on false or misleading information.
By setting forth specific prohibitions on unduly prejudicial and
discriminatory and deceptive practices, the proposed rule would
reinforce producers' and growers' existing rights to gather and share
information, while reducing the fear of retaliation and interference in
the contracting process. The prohibitions in the proposed rule would
also continue to support, and possibly promote more efficient and
equitable reducing information asymmetries and hold-up risk, reducing
retaliation, pretext, false and misleading information, and increasing
communication, cooperation, and retention of legal rights. The
prohibitions specified in proposed Sec. Sec. 201.304 and 201.306 would
ultimately assist in mitigating the impacts of imperfect competition.
[[Page 60042]]
Cost-Benefit Analysis of Proposed Sec. Sec. 201.304 and 201.306
Regulatory Alternatives Considered
Executive Order 12866 requires an assessment of costs and benefits
of potentially effective and reasonably feasible alternatives to the
planned regulations and an explanation of why the planned regulatory
action is preferable to the potential alternatives.\154\ AMS considered
three regulatory alternatives. The first alternative that AMS
considered is to maintain the status quo and not propose Sec. Sec.
201.304 and 201.306. The second alternative that AMS considered is to
issue proposed Sec. Sec. 201.304 and 201.306 as presented in this
proposed rule.\155\ This second alternative is AMS's preferred
alternative as will be explained below. The third alternative that AMS
considered is proposing Sec. Sec. 201.304 and 201.306, but exempting
small businesses, as defined by the Small Business Administration
(SBA), from having to comply with the recordkeeping requirement of
Sec. 201.304(c).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\154\ See Section 6(a)(3)(C) of Executive Order 12866.
\155\ This proposed rule includes Sec. 201.302, which defines a
covered producer, livestock producer, and regulated entity. These
definitions would apply to proposed Sec. Sec. 201.304 and 201.306.
The definitions proposed in Sec. 201.302 are captured in the
regulatory impacts of proposed Sec. Sec. 201.304 and 201.306. The
proposed rule also includes Sec. 201.390 which states all
provisions are severable in case any provision is declared invalid.
Proposed Sec. 201.390
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Regulatory Alternative 1: Status Quo Alternative
If proposed Sec. Sec. 201.304 and 201.306 are never promulgated,
there are no marginal costs and marginal benefits as industry
participants will not alter their conduct. From a cost standpoint, this
Status Quo Alternative is the least-cost alternative compared to the
other two alternatives. This alternative also has no marginal benefits.
Since there are no changes from the status quo under this regulatory
alternative, it will serve as the baseline against which to measure the
other two alternatives.
Regulatory Alternative 2: The Proposed Alternative
As discussed above, proposed Sec. 201.304 prohibits undue
prejudice, discrimination, and retaliation by regulated entities and
adds a requirement for regulated entities to maintain records, for a
period of five years, related to its compliance with proposed Sec.
201.304. Proposed Sec. 201.306 would prohibit deceptive practices by
regulated entities in contracting with covered producers including
making or modifying a contract, performing under or enforcing a
contract, terminating a contract, or refusing to contract with a
covered producer based on pretext, omission of information, or false or
misleading statements.
Regulatory Alternative 2: Benefits of the Proposed Alternative
Reductions in prejudicial, discriminatory, retaliatory, and
deceptive practices by packers, swine contractors, and live poultry
dealers would benefit livestock and poultry producers and growers.
These types of anticompetitive conduct do not have procompetitive
benefits and are generally conduct that occurs outside of written
contracts. Retaliation, for example, is not written into a contract,
but can occur by a packer terminating a contract based on pretext if a
livestock producer takes an action for which a packer disapproves, such
as joining a producer group that the packer denounces. There need not
be any changes to the contracting process or changes in the use of
marketing, production, or growing arrangements for producers and
growers to receive benefits. Any reductions in prejudicial,
discriminatory, retaliatory, and deceptive practices by packers, swine
contractors, and live poultry dealers would benefits producers and
growers. The amount of benefits that would be received by producers and
growers depends on the extent to which the proposed rule reduces
prejudicial, discriminatory, retaliatory, and deceptive practices.
That, in turn, is bounded by the degree to which any of these types of
activities are occurring in the baseline. The following discussion is
about the types of benefits that producers and growers would receive
from a reduction in prejudicial, discriminatory, retaliatory, and
deceptive practices by packers, swine contractors, and live poultry
dealers. If the reductions are small, the benefits would be small. The
greater the reductions, the greater the potential benefits.
AMS discusses the potential benefits to livestock producers and
growers from the Proposed Alternative (proposed Sec. Sec. 201.304 and
201.306) compared to the Status Quo Alternative. USDA's long-standing
policy has been that the P&S Act prohibits the type of conduct that the
Proposed Alternative (proposed Sec. Sec. 201.304 and 201.306)
addresses. The Proposed Alternative adds specificity to deceptive,
unjustly discriminatory practices (retaliation), and unreasonable
prejudices. Consequently, AMS expects packers, live poultry dealers,
and swine contractors would review the proposed rule and assess
compliance of their contracts and conduct with the proposed rule. Some
packers, swine contractors, and live poultry dealers may make some
minor modifications if they believe their contracts or conduct are not
in compliance. AMS expects all regulated entities to maintain relevant
records relating to their compliance with proposed Sec. 201.304, which
would provide further benefits to the industry.
The size of the benefits is difficult to quantify as they depend on
the amount of undue prejudice, discrimination, and deception that will
be avoided should the provisions in the Proposed Alternative be adopted
by the Agency. The more undue prejudice, discrimination, and deception
that will be avoided, the larger the benefits. AMS is unable to
quantify the benefits and will present a qualitative discussion of the
types of potential benefits that accrue from reductions in prejudice,
discrimination, retaliation, and deception.
The following discussion is for the benefits, in general, to the
livestock and poultry industries from the provisions in the Proposed
Alternative, and similar provisions that USDA has long viewed as
violations of P&S Act. The added benefits to the industry from the
Proposed Alternative over the Status Quo Alternative occur when
packers, swine contractors, and live poultry dealers alter their
contracts and/or conduct of their employees to reduce instances of
deceptive, prejudicial, and discriminatory practices, including
retaliation, and keep records about their compliance programs. The
potential benefits include protecting producer and grower rights,
improved corporate culture and the ability to investigate compliance
through recordkeeping requirement, addressing asymmetric information,
prohibiting deceptive practices, and other benefits.
Protecting Producer and Grower Rights
Concentration and lack of competition in livestock procurement
markets and poultry contracting can lead to abuses of market power such
as undue prejudice and discrimination, retaliation, deception, fraud,
and restrictions of producer and grower rights. A key purpose of
specifying certain prohibitions on unduly prejudicial, discriminatory,
and deceptive practices, including those in the Proposed Alternative,
is to protect livestock producers, swine contractors and poultry
growers' rights under the P&S Act. The Proposed Alternative would also
help protect producers and growers from unfair and deceptive practices
stemming from market power
[[Page 60043]]
imbalances such as undue prejudice, discrimination, retaliation, and
deception by using pretext and false and misleading information in
contracting by packers and live poultry dealers. These benefits of
prohibiting prejudicial, discriminatory, and deceptive practices,
including those in the proposed rule, would accrue not only to the
market's vulnerable and cooperative producers and growers who have been
subjected to the prohibited practices, but also to those for whom the
proposed rule's deterrence effects would protect from future potential
abuses.
For example, proposed Sec. 201.304(a)(1) and (2) in the Proposed
Alternative would prohibit undue prejudice and discrimination by
packers, swine contractors, and live poultry dealers against market
vulnerable producers and growers and cooperatives. This prohibition
would protect vulnerable producers and growers and cooperatives who
would potentially face these types of discrimination. Proposed Sec.
201.304(a)(3) in the Proposed Alternative includes examples of unduly
prejudicial and discriminatory conduct, including termination of
contracts, refusing to deal, and interference in farm real estate
transactions or contracts with third parties. Unfair termination of
contracts and refusal to deal can lead to an inefficient allocation of
resources.
Proposed Sec. 201.304(b)(1) in the Proposed Alternative would
prohibit packers, swine contractors, and live poultry dealers from
retaliating against producers and growers for engaging in certain
protected activities. Additionally, proposed Sec. 201.304(b)(2) would
protect producers and growers from retaliation by regulated entities
for engaging in various activities, including communicating with a
government agency, seeking redress before a court, or asserting rights
to join a producer or grower association, collectively process and
market livestock or poultry, or supporting or participating as a
witness in any proceeding under the P&S Act, or a proceeding that
relates to an alleged violation of law by a regulated entity. These
provisions would also protect producers and growers from retaliation
resulting from communication or cooperating with a person to improve
the production of livestock or poultry and from communicating with a
regulated entity to explore a business relationship. These types of
protections can improve market efficiency.
The Proposed Alternative's Sec. 201.306 would add a prohibition on
packers, swine contractors, and live poultry dealers of committing the
deceptive practices of pretext, providing false and misleading
information, or omission of material facts in forming, performing, and
terminating contracts and refusing to contract with producers and
growers with respect to livestock poultry and meat. Prohibitions on
deception could also improve efficiency by reducing instances where
resources are allocated based on pretext, false or misleading
information, or omission of material facts. That is, incorrect or
incomplete information can misguide the allocation of resources such as
land, labor, and capital away from their best use. The benefits of a
more efficient allocation of resources from these types of prohibitions
would be captured by producers, growers, packers, and live poultry
dealers. These types of benefits would be directly related to the
reduction in prejudicial, discriminatory, retaliatory, and deceptive
practices. These proposed provisions would further promote integrity in
the market and should give current and prospective producers and
growers more confidence that they would be treated fairly.
Recordkeeping
There are multiple potential benefits of the record-keeping
provision in the Proposed Alternative's proposed Sec. 201.304(c).
Record-keeping regulations can reduce AMS investigative costs and
improve the quality of the investigations. Access to essential records
would improve AMS enforcement and assist AMS in assessing the
effectiveness of the regulated entity's compliance with proposed Sec.
201.304(c). Information that AMS would gather when conducting
compliance reviews, can enable AMS to promote market competitiveness
and efficiency, as well as protect market participants against
discrimination and other abusive practices. The rights of vulnerable
producers and cooperatives can be better upheld when records of
regulated entities are maintained and can be reviewed by AMS.
Another potential benefit of the recordkeeping requirement in the
Proposed Alternative's Sec. 201.304(c) is that regulated entities
would know that AMS may be able to obtain and review records during
investigations. This may result in a change in corporate culture of
regulated entities in favor of increased voluntary compliance with
proposed Sec. 201.304 and reductions in undue prejudice,
discrimination, and retaliation because regulated entities would know
their records can be reviewed. Company leaders may shift the corporate
culture in order to comply with the proposed rule.
Addressing Asymmetric Information
Several provisions in the Proposed Alternative would enhance the
protection of the rights of producers and growers to lawfully
communicate and to associate with others to explore business
relationships and improve production practices and in the marketing of
livestock, poultry, and meat. These provisions would benefit producers
and growers by encouraging the use of their currently existing legal
rights to cooperate that would solidify and enhance their access to
information. This in turn, would help address information asymmetry and
thus help producers and growers make better business decisions, enhance
their competitiveness, reduce hold-up risk, and promote innovation and
economic efficiency in the industry.
The Proposed Alternative, by protecting the rights of growers and
producers to form associations and communicate freely with one another
and to communicate with other regulated entities for the purpose of
exploring a business relationship, would help close this information
gap. This would benefit producers and growers by improving industry
transparency, enhancing the bargaining power of supplier groups if they
elect to organize in such a way.
This proposed rule would prohibit retaliation against covered
producers due to their association with other producers and regulated
entities, which could increase the information available to growers
that is important in decision making. Improved safeguarding of
protected activities may enable the producer or grower to improve
business decision-making and manage risk, including potentially
acquiring external insurance and risk-management products. In addition,
facilitating producers and growers' ability to gain more and better
information would help correct information asymmetry and improve
transparency and completeness in contracts.
More information would also reduce the risks associated with hold-
up as discussed above. By protecting rights to freely communicate and
associate, this proposed rule would facilitate communication across the
industry that may help disseminate information regarding new
innovations and best practices within the industry. These types of
provisions that could provide producers and growers with access to more
and better information should promote innovation and economic
efficiency in the industry.
The Proposed Alternative may also serve to reduce the risk of
violating sec.
[[Page 60044]]
202(a) of the P&S Act because it would provide clarification to the
livestock and poultry industries as to the discriminatory and deceptive
practices that would be prohibited under that section of the Act. Less
risk through the clarification provided in the Proposed Alternative
would likely foster fairness in contracting by providing explicit
protections for livestock producers, swine production contract growers,
and poultry growers.
Prohibiting Deceptive Practices
Proposed Alternative's Sec. 201.306 specifies prohibited practices
that would be considered deceptive, and thus in violation of sec.
202(a) of the P&S Act. Though USDA already protects producers and
growers from deceptive practices, the proposed rule would explicitly
protect suppliers from deception by packers and live poultry dealers
from pretextual justifications, providing false and misleading
information, and the omission of material facts in contracting.
Prohibited deceptions, including false statements, pretext, or
omissions, can prevent or mislead producers and growers, sellers, or
buyers from making informed decisions and thus represents a market
inefficiency. The provisions in the Proposed Alternative would help
give producers and growers confidence that the information provided by
processors is reliable, which would help them to make better and more
informed business decisions and manage risk.
Other Benefits
While some of these protections already benefit individual
producers and growers, ensuring they cover the full marketplace and can
be enforced individually adds to the overall integrity and fairness of
livestock and poultry contracting. Specifying these protections may
bring additional benefits above the Status Quo Alternative.
Growing, production, and marketing contracting has many benefits in
the livestock and poultry industries. The Proposed Alternative can
further enhance the documented benefits of contracting by prohibiting
unduly prejudicial, discriminatory, and deceptive practices. Packers,
swine contractors, and live poultry dealers have at times exploited
their market power through business practices that have unjustly harmed
producers and livestock and poultry growers. These abuses have led to a
climate of fear among producers and growers that certain actions they
might undertake such as communication with government or other
regulated entities to pursue business relationships, association with
certain groups, or making lawful public complaints about the packers,
swine contractors, or live poultry dealers might result in harmful
retaliations. AMS intends the Proposed Alternative to promote integrity
to the marketplace by enhancing the protection of the rights of the
producers and growers and alleviating those fears.
The literature and data on these topics are not sufficient to allow
AMS to estimate the magnitude of the inefficiencies that the Proposed
Alternative may correct above the Status Quo Alternative, nor the
degree to which the additional producer and grower protections would
address inefficiencies. Though AMS is unable to quantify the benefits
of the proposed regulation, this analysis has explained the types of
benefits that would be derived from reductions in prejudice,
discrimination, retaliation, and deception. If the reductions are
small, the benefits would be small. The greater the reductions, the
greater the potential benefits.
Regulatory Alternative 2: Costs of the Proposed Alternative
Under the Proposed Alternative, the proposed rule would not impose
any restrictions on numbers or types of production or marketing
contracts that can be utilized, use of AMAs, tournaments, or base price
mechanisms in contracts for packers, swine contractors, and live
poultry dealers. Instead, the Proposed Alternative enhances the
prohibited unduly prejudicial, unjustly discriminatory, and deceptive
practices that AMS already considers violations of secs. 202(a) and
202(b) of the P&S Act. AMS does not expect the Proposed Alternative's
Sec. Sec. 201.304 and 201.306 to result in any measurable indirect
costs resulting from adjustments by the livestock and poultry
industries to reduce their use of AMAs, poultry tournaments, pricing
mechanisms, or to result in a significant number of substantial changes
to existing marketing or production contracts. Nor does AMS expect the
Proposed Alternative's Sec. Sec. 201.304 and 201.306 to have any
material effect on the quantity of meat or poultry produced.
Litigation Costs
AMS expects the Proposed Alternative's Sec. Sec. 201.304 and
201.306 to reduce litigation. The Proposed Alternative clarifies the
prohibited unduly prejudicial, discriminatory, and deceptive practices
that would violate sec. 202(a) of the P&S Act. The clarification could
result in a reduction in litigation costs if companies come into
compliance without any enforcement action. This regulation encourages
regulated entities to proactively avoid prejudicial, discriminatory,
and deceptive practices that could otherwise lead to costly litigation.
Further, some firms may develop policies and procedures to comply with
the proposed recordkeeping requirements. This effect could reduce
litigation and thus result in reduced litigation costs for regulated
entities.
However, there are several provisions in the Proposed Alternative's
Sec. 201.304 that could result in additional litigation. AMS has
received formal and informal complaints against packers, swine
contractors, and live poultry dealers for retaliation for belonging to
various producer and grower associations, contacting AMS to file a
complaint, asserting legal rights, and contacting a competing regulated
entity to pursue a contractual relationship. Similarly, there are
several provisions in the Proposed Alternative's Sec. 201.306 that
could result in additional litigation, including refusals by regulated
entities to enter into or renegotiate contracts and contract
terminations by producers and growers. The clarity of the practices
that AMS considers to be discriminatory and deceptive in the Proposed
Alternative's Sec. Sec. 201.304 and 201.306 could offer producers and
growers new hope for relief from courts for perceived undue
prejudicial, discriminatory, and deceptive practices by regulated
entities. This effect could result in increased litigation.
AMS is uncertain as to which effect will dominate and to what
extent. Given both effects, AMS does not expect large increases or
decreases in litigation from the proposed rule and, therefore, does not
estimate litigation costs in this analysis.
Direct Costs of the Proposed Option
AMS expects the Proposed Alternative's Sec. Sec. 201.304 and
201.306 would only result in direct administrative and recordkeeping
costs to the industry. AMS expects that packers, swine contractors, and
live poultry dealers would incur direct administrative costs of
learning the proposed rule and then reviewing and, if necessary,
revising marketing and production contracts to ensure compliance with
the Proposed Alternative's Sec. Sec. 201.304 and 201.306. Regulated
entities would also incur recordkeeping costs from keeping the records
required under the Proposed Alternative's Sec. 201.304. The expected
total costs of the Proposed Alternative's
[[Page 60045]]
Sec. Sec. 201.304 and 201.306 will be the direct administrative costs
and recordkeeping costs of that regulatory alternative. The direct
administrative costs and recordkeeping costs will be estimated below.
Direct Administrative Costs
AMS expects that the Proposed Alternative's Sec. Sec. 201.304 and
201.306 would prompt packers, live poultry dealers, and swine
contractors to first review and learn the proposed rule and then review
their procurement policies and production contracts and make any
necessary changes to ensure compliance with the new regulations.
Expected costs are estimated as the total value of the time required to
review and learn the rulemaking and then review and, if necessary,
revise procurement and production contracts.
AMS expects the direct administrative costs of complying with the
Proposed Alternative's Sec. Sec. 201.304 and 201.306 would be
relatively small. USDA policy has long held that several of the
provisions in the Proposed Alternative's Sec. Sec. 201.304 and 201.306
or similar provisions were violations of the P&S Act, although the
position has not been established in regulations. Consequently, AMS
expects packers, live poultry dealers, and swine contractors to make
changes to relatively few contracts.
Estimates of the amount of time required to review and learn the
proposed rule and to review and revise contracts and keep records were
provided by AMS subject matter experts. These experts were economists
and supervisors with many years of experience in AMS's PSD conducting
investigations and compliance reviews of regulated entities. In May
2020, U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) released Occupational
Employment and Wage Statistics that AMS used for the time values in
this analysis.\156\ BLS estimated an average hourly wage for general
and operations managers in animal slaughtering and processing to be
$65.84. The average hourly wage for lawyers in food manufacturing was
$80.39. In applying the cost estimates, AMS marked-up the wages by
41.56 percent to account for fringe benefits.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\156\ Estimates are available at U.S. Bureau of Labor
Statistics. Occupational Employment and Wage Statistics, available
at https://www.bls.gov/oes/special.requests/oesm20all.zip (accessed
8/9/2022).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
AMS expects that each packer, swine contractor, and live poultry
dealer would spend one hour of legal time and one hour of management
time to review and learn the rulemaking and then review and, if
necessary, revise production and marketing contracts to ensure
compliance with the rulemaking.
Live poultry dealers are currently required to file form PSD 3002,
``Annual Report of Live Poultry Dealers,'' OMB control number 0581-
0308, with AMS. Eighty-nine live poultry dealers filed annual reports
with AMS for their 2020 fiscal year.
Packers are currently required to file form PSD 3004, ``Annual
Report of Packers'' OMB control number 0581-0308, with AMS. Among other
things, each packer reports the number of head of cattle or calves,
hogs, and lamb, sheep, or goats that it processed. Three hundred sixty-
two packers that processed cattle or calves, hogs, or lamb, sheep or
goats filed reports with AMS for their fiscal year 2020. Two hundred
forty-eight were beef or veal packers. Two hundred eight were pork
packers, and 147 were lamb, sheep, or goat packers.\157\ The number of
beef, pork, and lamb packers do not sum to 362 because many firms
slaughtered more than one species of livestock. For instance, 119
packers slaughtered both beef and pork, and 75 slaughtered beef, pork,
and lamb.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\157\ For brevity, all beef and veal packers will be
collectively referred to as beef packers and all lamb, sheep, and
goat packers will be collectively referred to as lamb packers.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
AMS expects that packers processing more than one species of
livestock will not incur additional costs for each species. That is,
AMS expects that each packer will require one hour of attorney's time
and one hour of management time regardless of how many species of
livestock it processes. To allocate costs across (1) beef, (2) pork,
and (3) lamb processors, AMS allocated one-third of the costs to each
of (1) beef, (2) pork, and (3) lamb for packers that processed all
three species. For packers processing any two, AMS allocated one half
the costs to each.
AMS estimated that all live poultry dealers that are regulated
under the Proposed Alternative would require 1 hour of an attorney's
time costing the industry $10,000 \158\ and 1 hour of management time
costing the industry $8,000 \159\ for learning the rulemaking,
reviewing, and adjusting contracts. The total costs for learning,
reviewing, and adjusting contracts would be $18,000 \160\ for live
poultry dealers. AMS also expects that rulemaking will cost all 575
swine contractors an hour of an attorney's time and 1 hour of
management time costing a total of $119,000 across all swine
contractors.\161\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\158\ 89 live poultry dealers x $113.80 per hour x 1 hour =
$10,128.
\159\ 89 live poultry dealers x $93.20 per hour x 1 hour =
$8,295.
\160\ $10,128 + $8,295 = $18,423.
\161\ 575 x ($113.80 per hour x 1 hour + $93.20 per hour x 1
hour) = $119,027.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
AMS expects that packers would require an estimated 1 hour of an
attorney's time and 1 hour of management time costing the industry
$75,000.\162\ Pork packers' share of the packers' costs would be
$27,000. Combining costs to pork packers with costs to swine
contractors arrives at a total cost of $146,000 for hogs and pork
markets.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\162\ 362 x ($113.80 per hour x 1 hour + $93.20 per hour x 1
hour) = $74,935.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
AMS estimates that beef packers and lamb packers would also require
1 hour of attorney's time and 1 hour of management time to learn the
rulemaking, review, and revise contracts. The total costs for would be
$33,224 for beef packers and $14,697 for lamb packers.
Direct Recordkeeping Costs
As presented in detail in the Paperwork Reduction Act (PRA)
section, costs to comply with the proposed recordkeeping requirements
are likely relatively low. Proposed Sec. 201.304(c) requires specific
records that, if the regulated entity maintains, should be kept for a
period of five years, including policies and procedures, staff training
materials, materials informing covered producers regarding reporting
mechanisms and protections, compliance testing, board of directors'
oversight materials, and any records of the number and nature of unduly
prejudicial or discrimination-based complaints received.
Costs of recordkeeping, as described in detail in the PRA, include
regulated entities maintaining and updating compliance records, and is
considered a direct cost. Some smaller regulated entities that
currently don't maintain records, may voluntarily decide to develop
formal policies, procedures, training, etc. to comply with the
rulemaking and would then have records to maintain.
As described in detail in the PRA section, AMS expects the
recordkeeping costs would be comprised of the time required by
regulated entities to store and maintain records. AMS expects that the
costs will be relatively small because many packers, live poultry
dealers, and swine contractors may currently have few records
concerning policies and procedures, staff training materials, materials
informing covered producers regarding reporting mechanisms and
protections, compliance testing, and board of
[[Page 60046]]
directors' oversight materials related to prejudicial treatment. Some
smaller firms might not have any records to store. Others already store
the records and may have no new costs.
As described in detail in the PRA, AMS estimated that recordkeeping
time for larger entities will be greater than for smaller entities, and
thus estimated costs by quartiles, from largest entities to smallest.
AMS estimated that proposed Sec. 201.304(c) would require packers,
live poultry dealers, and swine contractors in each quartile an average
4.00 hours, 2.00 hours, 1.33 hours, and 0.67 hours of administrative
time for the first, second, third, and fourth quartiles, respectively.
Additionally, AMS estimated that the hours required of managers,
attorneys, and information technology staff each will average 1.50
hours, 0.75 hours, 0.50 hours, and 0.25 hours for the first, second,
third, and fourth quartiles, respectively.
As delineated in detail in the PRA, AMS also expects that packers,
live poultry dealers, and swine contractors will incur continuing
recordkeeping costs in each successive year. AMS estimated that
proposed Sec. 201.304(c) would require an average of 3.00 hours, 1.50
hours, 1.00 hour, and 0.50 hour of administrative assistant time; 1.50
hours, 0.75 hour, 0.50 hour, and 0.25 hour of time each from managers
and attorneys; and 1.00 hour, 0.50 hour, 0.33 hour, and 0.17 hour of
time from information technology staff for packers, live poultry
dealers, and swine contractors in the first, second, third, and fourth
quartiles, respectively, to setup and maintain the required records in
each succeeding year.
As described in detail in the PRA, estimated first-year costs for
recordkeeping requirements in proposed Sec. 201.304(c) total $26,000
for live poultry dealers,\163\ $170,000 for swine contractors,\164\ and
$107,000 for packers. Estimated yearly continuing costs for
recordkeeping requirements in Sec. 201.304(c) total $23,000 for live
poultry dealers,\165\ $147,000 for swine contractors,\166\ and $93,000
for packers.\167\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\163\ 89 live poultry dealers x (($39.69 per hour admin. cost x
(4 hours + 2 hours + 1.33 hours + .67 hours)) + ($93.20 per hour
manager cost x (1.5 hours + .75 hours + .5 hours + .25 hours)) +
($113.80 legal cost x (1.5 hours + .75 hours + .5 hours + .25
hours)) + ($82.50 information tech cost x (1.5 hours + .75 hours +
.5 hours + .25 hours))/4 = $26,390.
\164\ (575 swine contractors x (($39.69 per hour admin. cost x
(4 hours + 2 hours + 1.33 hours + .67 hours)) + ($93.20 per hour
manager cost x (1.5 hours + .75 hours + .5 hours + .25 hours)) +
(113.80 legal cost x (1.5 hours + .75 hours + .5 hours + .25 hours))
+ ($82.50 information tech cost x (1.5 hours + .75 hours + .5 hours
+ .25 hours)))/4 = $170,496.
\165\ (89 live poultry dealers x (($39.69 per hour admin. cost x
(4 hours + 2 hours + 1.33 hours + .67 hours)) + ($93.20 per hour
manager cost x (1.5 hours + .75 hours + .5 hours + .25 hours)) +
($113.80 legal cost x (1.5 hours + .75 hours + .5 hours + .25
hours)) + $82.50 information tech cost x (1.5 hours + .75 hours + .5
hours + .25 hours)))/4 = $22,788.
\166\ (575 swine contractors x (($39.69 per hour admin. cost x
(4 hours + 2 hours + 1.33 hours + .67 hours)) + ($93.20 per hour
manager cost x (1.5 hours + .75 hours + .5 hours + .25 hours)) +
($113.80 legal cost x (1.5 hours + .75 hours + .5 hours + .25
hours)) + ($82.50 information tech cost x (1.5 hours + .75 hours +
.5 hours + .25 hours)))/4 = $147,225.
\167\ (362 packers x ($39.69 per hour admin. cost x (4 hours + 2
hours + 1.33 hours + .67 hours)) + ($93.20 per hour manager cost x
(1.5 hours + .75 hours + .5 hours + .25 hours)) + ($113.80 legal
cost x (1.5 hours + .75 hours + .5 hours + .25 hours)) + ($82.50
information tech cost x (1.5 hours + .75 hours + .5 hours + .25
hours)))/4 = $92,688.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Breaking out costs by market, AMS expects recordkeeping
requirements in proposed Sec. 201.304(c) to cost beef packers $47,000
in the first year and $41,000 in each following year, as described in
detail in the PRA. Proposed Sec. 201.304(c) would cost lamb packers
$21,000 in the first year and $18,000 in successive years. Proposed
Sec. 201.304(c) would cost pork packers $39,000, and it would cost
swine contractors $170,000 for a total of $209,000 in the first year.
Proposed Sec. 201.304(c) would cost swine contractors $147,000 in
successive years, and it would cost pork packers $33,000 for a total
$180,000.
Total Direct Administrative and Recordkeeping Costs
The below table summarizes combined expected administrative and
recordkeeping costs for regulated entities in the first year and in
succeeding years. AMS expects that administrative and recordkeeping
costs associated with Proposed Alternative Sec. Sec. 201.304 and
201.306 would cost each packer, swine contractor, and live poultry
dealer an average $504 in the first year and an average $256 in each
succeeding year. First-year costs would total $45,000 for live poultry
dealers, $290,000 for swine contractors, and $182,000 for packers.
Costs in successive years would be due to recordkeeping requirements
and would total $23,000 for live poultry dealers, $147,000 for swine
contractors, and $93,000 for packers annually.
Table 7--Expected First-Year Cost and Succeeding Years Costs for Live
Poultry Dealers, Packers, and Swine Contractors
------------------------------------------------------------------------
Cost for each
First-year succeeding
cost ($) year ($)
------------------------------------------------------------------------
Average Cost per Live Poultry Dealer.... 504 256
Average Cost per to Swine Contractor.... 504 256
Average Cost per Packer................. 504 256
Total Cost to Live Poultry Dealers...... 45,000 23,000
Total Cost to Swine Contractors......... 290,000 147,000
Total Cost to Packers................... 182,000 ** 93,000
Beef Packers *...................... 80,000 41,000
Pork Packers *...................... 66,000 33,000
Lamb Packers *...................... 36,000 18,000
-------------------------------
Total Cost...................... 517,000 263,000
------------------------------------------------------------------------
* Many packers process more than one species of livestock, but AMS
expects that each packer will require one hour of attorney's time and
one hour of management time regardless of how many species of
livestock it processes. To allocate costs across (1) beef, (2) pork,
and (3) lamb processors, AMS allocated one-third of the costs to each
of (1) beef, (2) pork, and (3) lamb for packers that processed all
three species.
** Column total may not sum due to rounding.
[[Page 60047]]
The total direct administrative and recordkeeping costs are
estimated to be $517,000 in the first year. Estimated first year total
direct administrative and recordkeeping costs for the cattle and beef
industry, hogs and pork, lamb, and poultry industries rounded to the
nearest thousand dollars are listed in the following table.
Table 8--Direct Administrative and Recordkeeping Costs for Proposed Sec. Sec. 201.304 and 201.306 in 2022
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Cattle ($ Th) Hogs ($ Th) Lambs ($ Th) Poultry ($ Th) Total ($ Th)
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
80 355 36 45 517
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Regulatory Alternative 2--Proposed Alternative: Ten-Year Total Direct
Administrative and Recordkeeping Costs
Expected administrative and recordkeeping costs of proposed
Sec. Sec. 201.304 and 201.306 for each year from 2022 through 2031
appear in the table below.
Table 9--Ten-Year Total Direct Administrative and Recordkeeping Costs of Proposed Sec. Sec. 201.304 and
201.306 *
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Poultry ($
Year Cattle ($ Th) Hogs ($ Th) Lambs ($ Th) Th) Total ($ Th)
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
2022............................ 80 355 36 45 517
2023............................ 41 181 18 23 263
2024............................ 41 181 18 23 263
2025............................ 41 181 18 23 263
2026............................ 41 181 18 23 263
2027............................ 41 181 18 23 263
2028............................ 41 181 18 23 263
2029............................ 41 181 18 23 263
2030............................ 41 181 18 23 263
2031............................ 41 181 18 23 263
-------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Totals...................... 449 1,982 200 250 2,881
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
** Column total may not sum due to rounding.
Based on the analysis, AMS expects the ten-year total direct
administrative and recordkeeping costs of proposed Sec. Sec. 201.304
and 201.306 to be $2.9 million.
Regulatory Alternative 2--Proposed Alternative: Present Value of Ten-
Year Total Direct Administrative and Recordkeeping Costs
Costs to be incurred in the future are lower than the same costs to
be incurred today. This is because the money that will be used to pay
the costs in the future can be invested today and earn a return on
investment until the period in which the cost is incurred. After the
cost has been incurred, the earned returns will still be available.
To account for the time value of money, the administrative costs to
be incurred in the future are discounted back to today's dollars using
a discount rate. The sum of all costs discounted back to the present is
called the present value (PV) of total costs. AMS relied on both a
three percent and seven percent discount rate as discussed in Circular
A-4.\168\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\168\ Circular A-4. December 17, 2003, available at
www.whitehouse.gov/sites/whitehouse.gov/files/omb/circulars/A4/a-4.pdf (accessed 01/10/2022).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
AMS calculated the PV of the ten-year total direct administrative
and recordkeeping costs of the proposed regulations using a three
percent and seven percent discount rate and the PVs appear in the
following table.
[[Page 60048]]
Table 10--PV of Ten-Year Direct Administrative and Recordkeeping Cost of
Sec. Sec. 201.304 and 201.306
------------------------------------------------------------------------
Proposed
Discount rate alternative
($ th)
------------------------------------------------------------------------
3 Percent............................................... 2,487
7 Percent............................................... 2,082
------------------------------------------------------------------------
AMS expects the PV of the ten-year total administrative and
recordkeeping costs of proposed Sec. Sec. 201.304 and 201.306 to be
$2.5 million at a three percent discount rate and $2.1 million at a
seven percent discount rate.
Regulatory Alternative 2--Proposed Alternative: Annualized PV of Ten-
Year Total Direct Administrative and Recordkeeping Costs
AMS then annualized the PV of the ten-year total administrative and
recordkeeping costs (referred to as annualized costs) of proposed
Sec. Sec. 201.304 and 201.306 using both a three percent and seven
percent discount rate as required by Circular A-4 and the results
appear in the following table.\169\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\169\ Ibid.
Table 11--Annualized Direct Administrative and Recordkeeping Costs of
Proposed Sec. Sec. 201.304 and 201.306
------------------------------------------------------------------------
Proposed
Discount rate alternative
($ th)
------------------------------------------------------------------------
3 Percent............................................... 292
7 Percent............................................... 297
------------------------------------------------------------------------
AMS expects the annualized ten-year administrative and
recordkeeping costs of proposed Sec. Sec. 201.304 and 201.306 to be
$292,000 at a three percent discount rate and $297,000 at a seven
percent discount rate.
Cost-Benefit Comparison of Proposed Alternative
Combined sales of beef, pork, and broiler chicken in the U.S. for
2019 were approximately $240 billion. As discussed above, the total
cost of proposed Sec. Sec. 201.304 and 201.306 in the first year is
estimated to be $517,000, or 0.000002 percent of revenues. A reduction
in prejudicial, discriminatory, retaliatory, and deceptive practices
would lead to benefits that would be directly related to the reductions
in these practices. If the reductions are small, the benefits would be
small. The greater the reductions, the greater the benefits. AMS
expects that the net benefits to society from the proposed rule will be
very small in relation to the total value of industry production,
leading to negligible indirect effects on industry supply and demand,
including price and quantity effects.
Regulatory Alternative 3: Small Business Exemption Alternative
The third regulatory alternative that AMS considered is issuing
proposed Sec. Sec. 201.304 and 201.306, but exempting small
businesses, as defined by the SBA, from compliance with the
recordkeeping requirement of Sec. 201.304(c).\170\ All other
provisions of Sec. Sec. 201.304 and 201.306 would still apply to small
businesses. Most packers are small businesses under the SBA definition.
Of the 362 packers reporting to AMS, 346 are small businesses. Two
hundred forty-two beef packers and 197 pork packers are small
businesses. All 147 lamb packers are small businesses. Packers include
multi-species packers. One hundred eight swine contractors are small
businesses. There are 54 small poultry dealers.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\170\ See, ``Stay legally compliant (sba.gov),'' available at
https://www.sba.gov/business-guide/manage-your-business/stay-legally-compliant (Last accessed 8/9/2022).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Regulatory Alternative 3: Total Costs of the Small Business Exemption
Alternative
The below table summarizes combined expected administrative and
recordkeeping costs for regulated entities in the first year and in
succeeding years. AMS expects that administrative and recordkeeping
costs associated with Proposed Alternative Sec. Sec. 201.304 and
201.306 would cost each live poultry dealer, swine contractor, and
packer an average of $398, $485, $231, respectively, in the first year.
AMS expects costs to average $165, $256, and $23 for live poultry
dealers, swine contractors, and packers, respectively, in each
succeeding year. First-year costs would total $35,000 for live poultry
dealers, $279,000 for swine contractors, and $84,000 for packers. Costs
in successive years would be due to recordkeeping requirements and
would total $15,000 for live poultry dealers, $138,000 for swine
contractors, and $8,000 for packers annually. The total direct
administrative and recordkeeping costs are estimated to be $398,000 in
the first year.
Table 12--Small Business Record Keeping Exemption Alternative Expected
First-Year Cost and Succeeding Years Costs for Live Poultry Dealers,
Packers, and Swine Contractors
------------------------------------------------------------------------
Cost for each
First year succeeding
cost ($) year ($)
------------------------------------------------------------------------
Average Cost per Live Poultry Dealer.... 398 165
Average Cost per Swine Contractor....... 485 256
Average Cost per Packer................. 231 23
Total Cost to Live Poultry Dealers...... 35,000 15,000
Total Cost to Swine Contractors......... 279,000 138,000
Total Cost to Packers................... 84,000 8,000
Beef Packers *...................... 36,000 3,000
Pork Packers *...................... 33,000 5,000
Lamb Packers *...................... 15,000 0
-------------------------------
Total Cost...................... 398,000 161,000
------------------------------------------------------------------------
* Many packers process more than one species of livestock, but AMS
expects that each packer will require one hour of attorney's time and
one hour of management time regardless of how many species of
livestock it processes. To allocate costs across (1) beef, (2) pork,
and (3) lamb processors, AMS allocated one-third of the costs to each
of (1) beef, (2) pork, and (3) lamb for packers that processed all
three species.
[[Page 60049]]
As discussed above, AMS considers the total costs from proposed
Sec. Sec. 201.304 and 201.306 to be increased direct administrative
and recordkeeping costs with no indirect costs from adjustments by the
cattle, hog, and poultry industries to reduce their use of AMAs, change
pricing mechanisms or poultry tournaments, and no substantial changes
to existing marketing, growing, or production contracts. AMS estimated
the costs to small business from the direct administrative costs of
Sec. Sec. 201.304 and 201.306 but excluded the recordkeeping costs of
Sec. 201.304(c) in this alternative option.
AMS estimated the costs to small business to be the value of the
time for management, attorneys, administrative staff, and information
technology staff to review the rulemaking and the firms' practices
determining compliance with the direct administrative costs of
Sec. Sec. 201.304 and 201.306. AMS estimated costs for the Small
Business Exemption Alternative similarly to the Proposed Alternative.
The only difference is the recordkeeping costs of Sec. 201.304(c)
attributable to small business are not included in the costs for the
Small Business Exemption Alternative. The estimates appear in the table
below. The Proposed Alternative is also shown for convenience.
Table 13--Annual Total Direct Costs--Small Business Exemption
Alternative
------------------------------------------------------------------------
Small
Proposed business
Year alternative exemption
($ th) alternative
($ th)
------------------------------------------------------------------------
2022.......................................... 517 376
2023.......................................... 263 161
2024.......................................... 263 161
2025.......................................... 263 161
2026.......................................... 263 161
2027.......................................... 263 161
2028.......................................... 263 161
2029.......................................... 263 161
2030.......................................... 263 161
2031.......................................... 263 161
-------------------------
Totals.................................... 2,881 1,809
------------------------------------------------------------------------
AMS estimates that proposed Sec. Sec. 201.304 and 201.306, with
the small business exemption, will result in $376 thousand in direct
total costs in the cattle, hog, lamb, and poultry industries in the
first full year following implementation and $161 thousand each year in
ongoing costs. AMS expects the ten-year total costs of proposed
Sec. Sec. 201.304 and 201.306 with a small business exemption to be
$1.8 million. Exempting small business would save approximately
$140,000 in the first year and $1.1 million over ten years.
Regulatory Alternative 3: PV of Total Costs of the Small Business
Exemption Alternative
AMS calculated the PV of the ten-year total costs of the Small
Business Exemption Alternative using both a three percent and seven
percent discount rate and the PVs appear in the following table. The
Proposed Alternative is also shown for convenience.
Table 14--PV of Ten-Year Total Cost--Small Business Exemption
------------------------------------------------------------------------
Small
Proposed business
Discount rate alternative exemption
($ th) alternative
($ th)
------------------------------------------------------------------------
3 Percent............................... 2,487 1,567
7 Percent............................... 2,082 1,331
------------------------------------------------------------------------
AMS expects the PV of the ten-year total costs of proposed
Sec. Sec. 201.304 and 201.306 with a small business exemption to be
$1.6 million at a three percent discount rate and $1.3 million at a
seven percent discount rate.
Regulatory Alternative 3: Annualized Costs of the Small Business
Exemption Alternative
AMS then annualized the PV of the ten-year total costs of proposed
Sec. Sec. 201.304 and 201.306 with a small business exemption using
both a three percent and seven percent discount rate and the results
appear in the following table. The Proposed Alternative is also shown
for convenience.
Table 15--Ten-Year Annualized Costs--Small Business Exemption
------------------------------------------------------------------------
Small
Proposed business
Discount rate alternative exemption
($ th) alternative
($ th)
------------------------------------------------------------------------
3 Percent............................... 292 184
7 Percent............................... 297 190
------------------------------------------------------------------------
AMS expects the annualized costs of proposed Sec. Sec. 201.304 and
201.306 with a small business exemption to be $184,000 at a three
percent discount rate and $190,000 at a seven percent discount rate.
Cost-Benefit Comparison of Regulatory Alternatives
The status quo alternative has zero marginal costs. AMS compared
the annualized costs of the Proposed Alternative to the annualized
costs of the Small Business Exemption Alternative by subtracting the
annualized costs of the Small Business Exemption Alternative from those
of the Proposed Alternative and the results appear in the following
table.
Table 16--Difference in Ten-Year Annualized Costs of Proposed Sec. Sec.
201.304 and 201.306 Between Proposed Alternative and Small Business
Exemption Alternative
------------------------------------------------------------------------
Discount rate ($ th)
------------------------------------------------------------------------
3 Percent............................................... 108
7 Percent............................................... 107
------------------------------------------------------------------------
The annualized costs of the Small Business Exemption Alternative
are $108,000 less expensive using a three percent discount rate and
$107,000 less expensive using a seven percent discount rate. As is the
case with costs, the benefits will be highest for the Proposed
Alternative because the full benefits will be received by all livestock
producers and growers, not just those doing business with large
packers, swine contractors and live poultry dealers.
Though the Small Business Exemption Alternative would save between
$108,000 and $106,000 on an annualized basis, this alternative would
deny the potential benefits offered by proposed Sec. 201.304(c) to all
livestock producers, swine contract growers, and poultry growers who
contract with small packers, swine contractors, and live poultry
dealers. While most cattle, hogs, and poultry processed and grown are
contracted with large businesses, there are many small businesses who
would be exempt from keeping records under proposed Sec. 201.304(c) if
the Small Business Exemption Alternative is chosen. The Small Business
Exemption Alternative of the recordkeeping requirement of Sec.
201.304(c) would exempt all lamb processors and deny the potential
benefits to all lamb producers. Under this alternative, these livestock
producers, poultry growers and swine production contract growers would
be denied the potential benefits of recordkeeping and improved
corporate culture as discussed above in the section on Regulatory
Alternative 2: Benefits of the Proposed Alternative.
AMS considered all three regulatory alternatives and believes that
the Proposed Alternative is the best alternative as it benefits all
livestock producers, swine production contract growers, and poultry
growers, regardless of the size of the packer, swine contractor, or
live poultry dealer with
[[Page 60050]]
which they contract above the Status Quo Alternative.
Regulatory Flexibility Analysis
Proposed Sec. 201.304 prohibits retaliation by regulated entities
by terminating contracts, non-renewal of contracts, refusing to deal,
and interfering in farm real estate contracts as unduly prejudicial and
discriminatory practices. Proposed Sec. 201.306 prohibits deceptive
practices by regulated entities in contracting with covered producers
including making or modifying a contract, performing under or enforcing
a contract, terminating a contract, or refusing to contract with a
covered producer based on pretext, false or misleading statements, or
omission of material facts.
Additionally, the Proposed Alternative's Sec. 201.304(c) requires
packers, live poultry dealers, and swine contractors to keep relevant
records of policies and procedures, staff training materials, materials
informing covered producers regarding reporting mechanisms and
protections, compliance testing, and board of directors' oversight
materials related to prejudicial treatment.
The SBA defines small businesses by their North American Industry
Classification System Codes (NAICS).\171\ Live poultry dealers, NAICS
311615, are considered small businesses if they have fewer than 1,250
employees. Meat packers, including, beef, veal, pork, lamb, and goat
packers, NAICS 311611, are small businesses if they have fewer than
1,000 employees. Swine contractors, NAICS 112210, are considered small
if their sales are less than $1 million annually.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\171\ U.S. Small Business Administration. Table of Small
Business Size Standards Matched to North American Industry
Classification System Codes. effective August 19, 2019. ``The SBA
Issues a Final Rule to Adopt NAICS 2017 for Small Business Size''
(last accessed 8/9/2022). Available at https://www.sba.gov/article/2018/feb/27/sba-issues-final-rule-adopt-naics-2017-small-business-size-standards.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
AMS maintains data on live poultry dealers from the annual reports
these firms file with AMS. Currently, 89 live poultry dealers would be
subject to the proposed regulation. Fifty-four of the live poultry
dealers would be small businesses according to the SBA standard.
AMS records identified 362 packers that file annual reports with
PSD for their 2020 fiscal year. Two hundred forty-eight were beef
packers. Two hundred eight were pork packers, and 147 were lamb or goat
packers. Many firms slaughtered more than one species of livestock. For
instance, 118 packers slaughtered both beef and pork.
Most packers would be small businesses, although large packers are
responsible for most meat production. Three hundred forty-six packers
would be small businesses. Two hundred forty-two beef packers and 197
pork packers were small businesses. All of the 147 lamb and goat
packers were small businesses.
AMS does not have similar records for swine contractors because
they are not required to register with AMS or provide annual reports.
Table 24 of the 2017 USDA Census of Agriculture indicated that there
were 575 swine contractors in 2017. The Census of Agriculture table has
categories for the number of head that swine contractors sold, but not
the value of the head sold. AMS expects that the 467 swine contractors
that sold 5,000 head of hogs or more were large businesses, and the 108
contractors that sold less than 5,000 head were small businesses.
AMS estimated the costs in two parts. First, AMS expects that each
packer, swine contractor, and live poultry dealer would review and
learn the new rulemaking and then review and, if necessary, revise
production and marketing contracts to ensure compliance with the new
rulemaking. Second, AMS expects that packers, live poultry dealers, and
swine contractors would have additional costs associated with the new
recordkeeping requirements in proposed Sec. 201.304(c).
AMS estimated that costs reviewing and learning the Proposed
Alternative to small live poultry dealers, small packers, and small
swine contractors would consist of one hour of a manager's time and one
hour of a lawyer's time to review the requirements of proposed
Sec. Sec. 201.304 and 201.306. Expected first-year costs would be $207
\172\ for each live poultry dealer, each swine contractor, and each
packer. This would amount to a total $11,000 for the 54 live poultry
dealers, $72,000 for the 346 packers, and $22,000 for the 108 swine
contractors.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\172\ $113.80 per hour x 1 hour of an attorney's time + $93.20
per hour x 1 hour of a manager's time = $207.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Concerning the recordkeeping requirements in the Proposed
Alternative's Sec. 201.304(c), AMS expects the cost would be comprised
of the time required to store and maintain records. AMS expects that
the costs will be relatively small because packers, live poultry
dealers, and swine contractors would likely have few records concerning
policies and procedures, staff training materials, materials informing
covered producers regarding reporting mechanisms and protections,
compliance testing, and board of directors' oversight materials related
to prejudicial treatment. Many firms might not have any records to
maintain. Others already maintain the records and have no new costs.
AMS expects that recordkeeping costs would be correlated with the
size of the firms. AMS ranked packers, live poultry dealers, and swine
contractors by size and grouped them into quartiles, estimating more
recordkeeping time for larger entities than for the smaller entities.
AMS estimated that proposed Sec. 201.304(c) would require an average
of 4.00 hours of administrative assistant time, 1.50 hours of time each
from managers, attorneys, and information technology staff for packers,
live poultry dealers, and swine contractors in the first quartile,
containing the largest entities, to setup and maintain the required
records in the first year. AMS expects the packers, live poultry
dealers, and swine contractors in the second quartile would require an
average of 2.00 hours of administrative assistant time, 0.75 hours of
time each from managers, attorneys, and information technology staff
for first year costs. The third quartile would require 1.33 hours of
administrative assistant time, 0.50 hours of time each from managers,
attorneys, and information technology staff for first year costs, and
the fourth quartile, containing the smallest entities, would require
0.67 hours of administrative assistant time, 0.25 hours of time each
from managers, attorneys, and information technology staff.
AMS also expects that packers, live poultry dealers, and swine
contractors will incur continuing costs in each successive year. AMS
estimated that proposed Sec. 201.304(c) would require an average of
3.00 hours of administrative assistant time, 1.50 hours of time each
from managers and attorneys, and 1.00 hour of time from information
technology staff for packers, live poultry dealers, and swine
contractors in the first quartile to setup and maintain the required
records in each succeeding year. AMS expects the packers, live poultry
dealers, and swine contractors in the second quartile would require an
average of 1.50 hours of administrative assistant time, 0.75 hours of
time each from managers and attorneys, and 0.50 hours of time from
information technology staff in each succeeding year. The third
quartile would require 1.00 hour of administrative assistant time, 0.50
hours of time each from managers and attorneys, and 0.33 hours of time
from information technology staff in each succeeding year, and the
fourth quartile would require 0.50 hours
[[Page 60051]]
of administrative assistant time, 0.25 hours of time each from managers
and attorneys, and 0.17 hours from information technology staff.
Estimated first-year costs for recordkeeping requirements in the
Proposed Alternative's Sec. 201.304(c) totaled $9,000 for live poultry
dealers,\173\ $11,000 for swine contractors,\174\ and $98,000 for
packers.\175\ Estimated yearly continuing costs for recordkeeping
requirements in Sec. 201.304(c) totaled $8,000 for live poultry
dealers,\176\ $9,000 for swine contractors,\177\ and $84,000 for
packers.\178\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\173\ 9.5 live poultry dealers x ($39.69 per hour admin. cost x
2 hours + $93.20 per hour manger cost x .75 + $113.80 legal cost x
.75 hours + $82.50 information tech cost x .75 hours) + 44.5 live
poultry dealers x ($39.69 per hour admin. cost x (1.33 hours + .67
hours) + $93.20 per hour manger cost x (.5 hours + .25 hours) +
$113.80 legal cost x (.5 hours + .25 hours) + $82.50 information
tech cost x (.5 hours + .25 hours))/2 = $9,414.
\174\ 108 swine contractors x ($39.69 per hour admin. cost x .67
hours + $93.20 per hour manger cost x .25 hours + $113.80 legal cost
x .25 hours + $82.50 information tech cost x .25 hours) = $10,675.
\175\ 74.5 packers x ($39.69 per hour admin. cost x 2 hours +
$93.20 per hour manger cost x .75 hours + $113.80 legal cost x .75
hours + $82.50 information tech cost x .75 hours + 271.5 packers x
($39.69 per hour admin. cost x (2 hours + 1.33 hours + .67 hours) +
$93.20 per hour manger cost x (.75 hours + .5 hours + .25 hours) +
$113.80 legal cost x (.75 hours + .5 hours + .25 hours) + $82.50
information tech cost x (.75 hours + .5 hours + .25 hours))/3 =
$97,850.
\176\ 9.5 live poultry dealers x ($39.69 per hour admin. cost x
1.5 hours + $93.20 per hour manger cost x .75 + $113.80 legal cost x
.75 hours + $82.50 information tech cost x .75 hours) + 44.5 live
poultry dealers x ($39.69 per hour admin. cost x (1 hours + .5
hours)) + $93.20 per hour manger cost x (.5 hours + .25 hours)) +
($113.80 legal cost x (.5 hours + .25 hours) + ($82.50 information
tech cost x (.33hours + .17 hours))/2 = $8,129.
\177\ 108 swine contractors x ($39.69 per hour admin. cost x .5
hours + $93.20 per hour manger cost x .25 hours + $113.80 legal cost
x .25 hours + $82.50 information tech cost x .17 hours) = $9,217.
\178\ 74.5 packers x ($39.69 per hour admin. cost x 3 hours +
$93.20 per hour manger cost x 1.5 hours + $113.80 legal cost x 1.5
hours + $82.50 information tech cost x 1 hour) + 271.5 packers x
($39.69 per hour admin. cost x (1.5 hours + 1 hours + .5 hours) +
$93.20 per hour manger cost x (.75 hours + .5 hours + .25 hours) +
$113.80 legal cost x (.75 hours + .5 hours + .25 hours) + $82.50
information tech cost x (.50 hours + .33 hours + .17 hours))/3 =
$84,494.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Total expected first year costs, including one time reviewing costs
and recordkeeping cost would be $169,000 for packers, $33,000 for swine
contractors, and $21,000 for live poultry dealers. Table 17 lists
expected costs for small businesses subject to proposed Sec. Sec.
201.304 and 201.306. AMS expects marginal costs to total $223,000 in
the first year. Ten-year costs annualized at 3 percent would be $94,000
for packers, $12,000 for swine contractors, and $10,000 for live
poultry dealers. Total ten-year costs annualized at 3 percent would be
expected to be $116,000.
Ten-year costs annualized at 7 percent would be $96,000 for
packers, $12,000 for swine contractors, and $10,000 for live poultry
dealers. Total ten-year costs annualized at 7 percent would be expected
to be $118,000.
Table 17--Estimated Industry Total Costs to Small Businesses
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Swine Poultry
Estimate type Packers ($) contractors processors Total ($)
($) ($)
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
First-Year Costs................................ 169,000 33,000 21,000 223,000
10 years Annualized at 3 Percent................ 94,000 12,000 10,000 116,000
10 years Annualized at 7 Percent................ 96,000 12,000 10,000 118,000
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Live poultry dealers annually file reports with AMS that list each
firm's net sales. Packers that purchase more than $500,000 annually in
livestock also file annual reports that list net sales. While packers
that annually slaughter less than $500,000 in livestock also file
annual reports with AMS, in order to reduce the reporting requirements
for small packers, they are not required to provide annual net sales.
Data from the annual reports enables AMS to compare average net
sales for small pork packers, beef packers, and live poultry dealers to
the expected costs of proposed Sec. Sec. 201.304 and 201.306 in the
table below. A shortcoming in the comparison is that net sales for
smallest packers, those that purchase less than $500,000 in livestock,
are not included in the average.
Swine contractors are not required to file annual reports with AMS,
and similar net sales data are not available for swine contractors.
Census of Agriculture's data have the number of head sold by size
classes for farms that sold their own hogs and pigs in 2017 and that
identified themselves as contractors or integrators, but not the value
of sales nor the number of head sold from the farms of the contracted
production. To estimate average revenue per establishment, AMS used the
estimated average value per head for sales of all swine operations and
the production values for firms in the Agriculture Census size classes
for swine contractors.
The following table compares the average per entity first-year
costs of the Proposed Alternative's Sec. Sec. 201.304 and 201.306 to
the average revenue per establishment for all regulated small
businesses. First-year costs are appropriate for a threshold analysis
because all the costs would occur in the first year. First-year costs
per regulated entity are considerably higher than annualized costs, and
any ratio of annualized costs to revenues will be less than a ratio of
first-year costs to revenues.
Table 18--Comparison of Average Costs per Entity to Average Revenues per Entity for Small Businesses
--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
First-year Annualized
Number of Average revenue cost as Annualized cost as
NAICS small or net sales per First-year percent of cost percent of
businesses establishment costs ($) revenue discounted at revenue
($) (percent) 7% (percent)
--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
112210--Swine Contractor............................. 108 485,860 306 0.0629 115 0.0236
311615--Poultry Processor............................ 54 50,729,044 381 0.0008 181 0.0004
[[Page 60052]]
311611--Meat Packer *................................ 346 83,356,860 490 0.0006 277 0.0003
--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
* Averages exclude net sales for packers that purchased less than $500,000 in livestock annually.
First-year costs as a percent of revenues are small. It is highest
for swine contractors because average revenues for swine contractors
are considerably smaller than average revenues for packers and live
poultry dealers. At 0.0629 percent, the first-year cost is small
compared to revenue.
Average net sales for packers listed in Table 18 have the problem
of excluding the smallest packers, and consequently the averages are
biased toward being too large. However, first-year cost as a percent of
net sales is 0.0006 percent. Estimated first year cost for each packer
is $490. These are relatively small numbers. If average net sales for
each packer were only one hundredth of the amount listed in Table 18,
estimated first-year costs would be less than 0.1 percent of net sales.
AMS has limited data on revenues for the smallest packers and live
poultry dealers. Eighty-five packers submitted shortened annual reports
to AMS because they purchased less than $500,000 in livestock. For the
largest of these packers, annual revenues are likely close to $500,000
and expected costs would be about 0.06 percent. AMS encourages comments
concerning business sizes for packers that purchase less than $500,000
in livestock each year and the effect the proposed Sec. Sec. 201.304
and 201.306 would have on their business.
Small Business Exception Alternative
AMS also considered a Small Business Exception Alternative to the
Proposed Alternative's Sec. Sec. 201.304 and 201.306. The Small
Business Exception Alternative would be the same as the Proposed
Alternative's Sec. Sec. 201.304 and 201.306 in all respects with the
exception that none of the recordkeeping requirements in proposed Sec.
201.304(c) would apply to small businesses. This Small Business
Exception Alternative would cost small packers, swine contractors, and
live poultry dealers less than proposed Sec. Sec. 201.304 and 201.306
would cost. Recordkeeping costs comprised the largest share of the
costs associated with Sec. Sec. 201.304 and 201.306.
Although the Small Business Exception Alternative would not require
small businesses to keep any additional records, small businesses would
still be required to comply with all of the other provisions of
Sec. Sec. 201.304 and 201.306. AMS expects that small live poultry
dealers, small packers, and small swine contractors would need to
review the new rulemaking and determine whether the proposed rule would
require any changes to their procurement contracts or other business
practices and make the necessary changes. AMS estimated that costs
would consist of one hour of a manager's time and one hour of a
lawyer's time to review the requirements of Proposed Alternative's
Sec. Sec. 201.304 and 201.306. This amounts to expected first-year
costs of $207 \179\ for each live poultry dealer, each swine
contractor, and each packer that qualifies as small business. All costs
would occur in the first year.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\179\ $113.80 per hour x 1 hour of an attorney's time + 93.20
per hour x 1 hour of a manager's time = $207.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Table 19 lists expected costs for small businesses subject to the
Small Business Exception Alternative. AMS expects marginal costs to
total $105,000 in the first year. The Small Business Exception
Alternative is expected to cost $72,000, $22,000, and $11,000 for
packers, swine contractors, and live poultry dealers respectively.
Table 19--Estimated Industry Total Costs for the Small Business Exception Alternative
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Swine
Estimate type Packers ($) contractors Poultry Packers ($)
($) processors ($)
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
First-Year Costs................................ 72,000 22,000 11,000 105,000
10 years Annualized at 3 Percent................ 8,000 3,000 1,000 12,000
10 years Annualized at 7 Percent................ 10,000 3,000 1,000 14,000
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Ten-year costs annualized at 3 percent would be $8,000 for packers,
$3,000 for swine contractors, and $1,000 for live poultry dealers. This
amounts to $24 for each live poultry dealer, swine contractor, and
packer. Total ten-year costs annualized at 3 percent would be expected
to be $12,000.
Ten-year costs annualized at 7 percent would be $10,000 for
packers, $3,000 for swine contractors, and $1,000 for live poultry
dealers. This amounts to $28 for each live poultry dealer, swine
contractor, and packer. Total ten-year costs annualized at 3 percent
would be expected to be $14,000.
Table 20 compares the average per entity first-year costs of the
Small Business Exception Alternative to the average revenue for each
regulated small business. First-year costs are appropriate for a
threshold analysis because all of the costs associated with the
alternative would occur in the first year.
[[Page 60053]]
Table 20--Comparison of per Entity Cost to Revenues for the Small Business Exception Alternative
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Average revenue First-year cost
NAICS Number of small First-year costs or net sales per as percent of
businesses ($) Establishment ($) revenue (percent)
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
112210--Swine Contractor............ 108 207 485,860 0.0426
311615--Poultry Processor........... 54 207 50,729,044 0.0004
311611--Meat Packer *............... 346 207 83,356,860 0.0002
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
* Averages exclude net sales for packers that purchased less than $500,000 in livestock annually.
First-year costs as a percent of revenues are small. Similar to
proposed Sec. Sec. 201.304 and 201.306, relative costs are highest for
swine contractors because average revenues for swine contractors are
considerably smaller than average revenues for packers and live poultry
dealers. At 0.0426 percent, the first-year cost to swine contractors is
small compared to revenue.
Average net sales for packers listed in Table 18 have the same
problem as the net sales figures in Table 16. They exclude the smallest
packers, and consequently the averages are biased toward being too
large. However, first-year cost as a percent of net sales for packers
purchasing more than $500,000 per year is 0.0002 percent. Estimated
first year cost for each packer is $207. Costs would be less than 0.1
percent of revenues for any packer with revenue greater than $20,700.
Even for the smallest packer that AMS regulates, $207 would not likely
have a significant economic impact.
Comparison of Alternatives
Expected costs for small businesses under the Proposed
Alternative's Sec. Sec. 201.304 and 201.306 would be more than double
the expected costs for small businesses under a Small Business
Exception Alternative. The cost difference is due to recordkeeping
requirements. First-year costs would be $128,000 more for the Proposed
Alternative than the Small Business Exception Alternative. While all of
the costs associated with the Small Business Exception Alternative
occur in the first year, small businesses would continue to incur
recordkeeping costs associated with the Proposed Alternative Sec. Sec.
201.304 and 201.306 into the future. Estimated costs annualized at 7
percent are $104,000 higher for Proposed Alternative Sec. Sec. 201.304
and 201.306 than for the Small Business Exemption Alternative.
With either the Small Business Exception Alternative, or the
Proposed Alternative, AMS expects the costs to be relatively small. The
number of regulated entities that could experience a cost increase is
substantial. Most regulated packers and live poultry dealers are small
businesses. However, AMS expects that few small businesses would
experience significant costs. For all three groups of regulated
entities: packers, live poultry dealers, and swine contractors, average
first year costs are expected to amount to less than one 0.1 percent of
annual revenue for either of the alternatives. AMS expects that any
additional costs to small packers, live poultry dealers, and swine
contractors from this proposed rulemaking will not change their ability
to continue operations or place any small businesses at a competitive
disadvantage.
AMS chose the Proposed Alternative's Sec. Sec. 201.304 and 201.306
over the Small Business Exception Alternative because AMS wishes to
prevent the kind of undue prejudices and discrimination described in
the proposed rule. AMS believes that keeping relevant records serves as
constant reminder to all packers, live poultry dealers, and swine
contractors that they cannot purchase livestock or enter into contracts
for growing services with the kind of undue prejudices and
discrimination described in the rulemaking.
The Proposed Alternative's Sec. Sec. 201.304 and 201.306 are not
expected to have a significant economic impact on a substantial number
of small business entities as defined in the Regulatory Flexibility Act
(5 U.S.C. 601 et seq.). While confident in this assertion, AMS
acknowledges that individual businesses may have relevant data to
supplement our analysis. AMS encourages small stakeholders to submit
any relevant data during the comment period.
E-Government Act
USDA is committed to complying with the E-Government Act by
promoting the use of the internet and other information technologies to
provide increased opportunities for citizen access to Government
information and services, and for other purposes.
Executive Order 13175--Consultation and Coordination With Indian Tribal
Governments
This proposed rule has been reviewed in accordance with the
requirements of E.O. 13175--Consultation and Coordination with Indian
Tribal governments. E.O. 13175 requires Federal agencies to consult
with tribes on a government-to-government basis on policies that have
tribal implications, including regulations, legislative comments or
proposed legislation, and other policy statements or actions that have
substantial direct effects on one or more Indian tribes, on the
relationship between the Federal Government and Indian tribes or the
distribution of power and responsibilities between the Federal
Government and Indian tribes.
This proposed rule will impact individual members of Indian Tribes
and will impact Tribal governments or instrumentalities of Tribal
governments. The rulemaking will also impact the relationship between
Tribes and the Federal Government. USDA will hold a consultation with
Tribal governments regarding the impact of this proposed rule with
respect to Tribal governments and Native American livestock producers.
USDA also seeks comments and information from Tribal organizations
concerning impact on individual American Indian/Alaska Native livestock
producers. Additional details on the date and manner of the
consultations will be announced in a ``Dear Tribal Leader Letter,'' to
be sent individually to tribes and published on the USDA Office of
Tribal Relations website at https://www.usda.gov/tribalrelations/tribal-consultations.
Civil Rights Impact Analysis
AMS has considered the potential civil rights implications of this
proposed rule on members of protected groups to ensure that no person
or group would be adversely or disproportionately at risk or
discriminated against on the basis of race, color, national origin,
gender, religion, age, disability, sexual orientation, marital or
family status, or protected genetic information. This
[[Page 60054]]
rulemaking does not contain any requirements related to eligibility,
benefits, or services that would have the purpose or effect of
excluding, limiting, or otherwise disadvantaging any individual, group,
or class of persons on one or more prohibited bases. In fact, the
proposed regulation would create means by which AMS may be able to
address potential civil rights issues in violation of the Act.
In its review, AMS conducted a disparate impact analysis, using the
required calculations, which resulted in a finding that Asian
Americans, American Indian/Alaskan Natives, Pacific Islanders, and
Native Hawaiians were disproportionately impacted. AMS analysis
reflects that most producers and poultry growers will experience
greater access to information regarding acquiring, handling, and
processing quality livestock. The proposed regulation provides clearer
standards to address market disadvantages to small and medium scale
producers and growers, contributing to favorable contract terms and
equitable price premiums.
AMS will institute enhance efforts to notify the groups found to be
more significantly impacted of the regulations and their implications.
AMS outreach will specifically target several organizations that
regularly engage with or otherwise may represent the interests of these
impacted groups. As a result of this outreach, if AMS detects the
possibility of the new regulation causing a potential disparate impact
on any protected individual or group, AMS will develop a mitigation
strategy.
Executive Order 12988--Civil Justice Reform
This proposed rule has been reviewed under Executive Order 12988--
Civil Justice Reform. This proposed rule is not intended to have
retroactive effect. This proposed rule would not preempt state or local
laws, regulations, or policies, unless they present an irreconcilable
conflict with this rulemaking. There are no administrative procedures
that must be exhausted prior to any judicial challenge to the
provisions of this proposed rule. Nothing in this proposed rule is
intended to interfere with a person's right to enforce liability
against any person subject to the Act under authority granted in sec.
308 of the Act.
VI. Request for Comments
Comments submitted on or before December 2, 2022 will be
considered. Comments should reference Docket No. AMS-FTPP-21-0045 and
the date and page number of this issue of the Federal Register.
Comments can be submitted by either of the following methods:
Federal eRulemaking Portal: Go to https://www.regulations.gov. Enter AMS-FTPP-21-0045 in the Search filed. Select
the Documents tab, then select the Comment button in the list of
documents.
Postal Mail/Commercial Delivery: Send your comment to
Docket No. AMS-FTPP-21-0045, S. Brett Offutt, Chief Legal Officer,
Packers and Stockyards Division, USDA, AMS, FTPP; Room 2097-S, Mail
Stop 3601, 1400 Independence Ave. SW, Washington, DC 20250-3601.
List of Subjects in 9 CFR Part 201
Confidential business information, Reporting and recordkeeping
requirements, Stockyards, Surety bonds, Trade practices.
For the reasons set forth in the preamble, AMS proposes to amend 9
CFR part 201 as follows:
PART 201--ADMINISTERING THE PACKERS AND STOCKYARDS ACT
0
1. The authority citation for 9 CFR part 201 continues to read as
follows:
Authority: 7 U.S.C. 181-229c.
0
2. Add subpart O, consisting of Sec. Sec. 201.300 through 201.390, to
read as follows:
Subpart O--Competition and Market Integrity
Sec.
201.300-201.301 [Reserved]
201.302 Definitions.
201.304 Undue prejudices or disadvantages and unjust discriminatory
practices.
201.306 Deceptive practices.
201.307-201.389 [Reserved]
201.390 Severability.
Sec. Sec. 201.300-201.301 [Reserved]
Sec. 201.302 Definitions.
For purposes of this subpart, the following definitions apply:
Covered producer means a livestock producer as defined in this
section or a swine production contract grower or poultry grower as
defined in section 2(a) of the Act (7 U.S.C. 182(8), (14)).
Livestock producer means any person engaged in the raising and
caring for livestock by the producer or another person, whether the
livestock is owned by the producer or by another person, but not an
employee of the owner of the livestock.
Market vulnerable individual means a person who is a member, or who
a regulated entity perceives to be a member, of a group whose members
have been subjected to, or are at heightened risk of, adverse treatment
because of their identity as a member or perceived member of the group
without regard to their individual qualities. A market vulnerable
individual includes a company or organization where one or more of the
principal owners, executives, or members would otherwise be a market
vulnerable individual.
Regulated entity means a swine contractor or live poultry dealer as
defined in section 2(a) of the Act (7 U.S.C. 182(8)) or a packer as
defined in section 201 of the Act (7 U.S.C. 191).
Sec. 201.304 Undue prejudices or disadvantages and unjust
discriminatory practices.
(a) Prohibited bases. (1) A regulated entity may not prejudice,
disadvantage, inhibit market access, or otherwise take adverse action
against a covered producer with respect to any matter related to
livestock, meats, meat food products, livestock products in
unmanufactured form, or live poultry based upon the covered producer's
status as a market vulnerable individual or as a cooperative.
(2) Prejudice or disadvantage with respect to paragraph (a)(1) of
this section includes the following actions:
(i) Offering contract terms that are less favorable than those
generally or ordinarily offered.
(ii) Refusing to deal.
(iii) Differential contract performance or enforcement.
(iv) Termination of a contract or non-renewal of a contract.
(b) Retaliation prohibited. (1) A regulated entity may not
retaliate or otherwise take an adverse action against a covered
producer because of the covered producer's participation in the
activities described in paragraph (b)(2) of this section to the extent
that these activities are not otherwise prohibited by Federal or state
law, including antitrust laws.
(2) The following activities are protected under paragraph (b)(1)
of this section:
(i) A covered producer communicates with a government agency with
respect to any matter related to livestock, meats, meat food products,
livestock products in unmanufactured form, or live poultry or petitions
for redress of grievances before a court, legislature, or government
agency.
(ii) A covered producer asserts any of the rights granted under the
Act or this part, or asserts contract rights.
(iii) A covered producer asserts the right to form or join a
producer or grower association or organization, or to collectively
process, prepare for market, handle, or market livestock or poultry.
[[Page 60055]]
(iv) A covered producer communicates or cooperates with a person
for the purposes of improving production or marketing of livestock or
poultry.
(v) A covered producer communicates or negotiates with a regulated
entity for the purpose of exploring a business relationship.
(vi) A covered producer supports or participates as a witness in
any proceeding under the Act, or a proceeding that relates to an
alleged violation of law by a regulated entity.
(3) For purposes of paragraph (b)(1) of this section, retaliation
includes the following actions:
(i) Termination of contracts or non-renewal of contracts.
(ii) Adversely differential performance or enforcement of a
contract.
(iii) Refusing to deal with a covered producer.
(iv) Interference in farm real estate transactions or contracts
with third parties.
(c) Recordkeeping of compliance practices. (1) The regulated entity
shall retain all records relevant to its compliance with paragraphs (a)
and (b) of this section for no less than 5 years from the date of
record creation.
(2) Records that may be relevant under paragraph (c)(1) of this
section include, if any, policies and procedures, staff training
materials, materials informing covered producers regarding reporting
mechanisms and protections, compliance testing, board of directors'
oversight materials, and the number and nature of complaints received
relevant to this section.
Sec. 201.306 Deceptive practices.
(a) Prohibited practices. A regulated entity may not engage in the
specific deceptive practices prohibited in paragraphs (b) through (e)
of this section with respect to any matter related to livestock, meats,
meat food products, livestock products in unmanufactured form, or live
poultry.
(b) Contract formation. A regulated entity may not make or modify a
contract by employing a pretext, false or misleading statement, or
omission of material fact necessary to make a statement not false or
misleading.
(c) Contract performance. A regulated entity may not perform under
or enforce a contract by employing a pretext, false or misleading
statement, or omission of material fact necessary to make a statement
not false or misleading.
(d) Contract termination. A regulated entity may not terminate a
contract or take any other adverse action against a covered producer by
employing a pretext, false or misleading statement, or omission of
material fact necessary to make a statement not false or misleading.
(e) Contract refusal. A regulated entity may not provide false or
misleading information to a covered producer or association of covered
producers concerning a refusal to contract.
Sec. Sec. 201.307-201.389 [Reserved]
Sec. 201.390 Severability.
If any provision of this subpart is declared invalid or the
applicability thereof to any person or circumstances is held invalid,
the validity of the remainder of this subpart or the applicability
thereof to other persons or circumstances shall not be affected
thereby.
Erin Morris,
Associate Administrator, Agricultural Marketing Service.
[FR Doc. 2022-21114 Filed 9-30-22; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 3410-02-P