Qualifying Facility Rates and Requirements Implementation Issues Under the Public Utility Regulatory Policies Act of 1978, 54638-54740 [2020-15902]
Download as PDF
54638
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
In this Order, the Federal
Energy Regulatory Commission issues
its final rule approving certain revisions
to its regulations implementing sections
201 and 210 of the Public Utility
Regulatory Policies Act of 1978
(PURPA). These changes will enable the
Commission to continue to fulfill its
statutory obligations under sections 201
and 210 of PURPA.
DATES: This rule is effective December
31, 2020.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
Lawrence R. Greenfield (Legal
Information), Office of the General
Counsel, Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission, 888 First Street NE,
SUMMARY:
DEPARTMENT OF ENERGY
Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission
18 CFR Parts 292 and 375
[Docket Nos. RM19–15–000 and AD16–16–
000; Order No. 872]
Qualifying Facility Rates and
Requirements Implementation Issues
Under the Public Utility Regulatory
Policies Act of 1978
Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission.
ACTION: Final rule.
AGENCY:
Washington, DC 20426, (202) 502–6415,
lawrence.greenfield@ferc.gov.
Helen Shepherd (Technical
Information), Office of Energy Market
Regulation, Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission, 888 First Street NE,
Washington, DC 20426, (202) 502–6176,
helen.shepherd@ferc.gov.
Thomas Dautel (Technical
Information), Office of Energy Policy
and Innovation, Federal Energy
Regulatory Commission, 888 First Street
NE, Washington, DC 20426, (202) 502–
6196, thomas.dautel@ferc.gov.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION:
Table of Contents
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
Paragraph
Nos.
I. Introduction ...........................................................................................................................................................................................
II. Overview ..............................................................................................................................................................................................
A. The Commission’s PURPA Regulations, as Revised by This Final Rule, Continue To Encourage the Development of QFs
Within the Requirements of PURPA’s Statutory Limitations .....................................................................................................
1. Avoided Cost Cap on QF Rates .............................................................................................................................................
2. Limitation on Small Power Production Facilities Located at the Same ‘‘Site’’ .................................................................
3. Termination of Purchase Obligation for QFs With Nondiscriminatory Access to Certain Competitive Markets ...........
4. Final Rule’s Updating of the PURPA Regulations ...............................................................................................................
B. The Final Rule Ensures That the Commission’s Implementation of PURPA Continues To Benefit QFs, Purchasing Electric Utilities, and Electric Consumers ..........................................................................................................................................
C. The Commission Is Not Eliminating Fixed Rate Pricing for QFs, But Rather Is Giving States the Flexibility To Require
the Same Variable Energy Rate/Fixed Capacity Rate Construct That Applies Throughout the Electric Industry ..................
D. The Rate Changes Implemented by This Final Rule Put QF Rates on the Same Footing as Electric Utility Rates and Are
Not Discriminatory ........................................................................................................................................................................
E. The PURPA Compliance Issues Raised by Some Commenters Are Outside the Scope of This Rulemaking Proceeding .....
III. Background .........................................................................................................................................................................................
A. Passage of PURPA in 1978 and the Commission’s Promulgation of Its PURPA Regulations in 1980 ...................................
B. Circumstances Leading to the Commission’s Re-evaluation of the PURPA Regulations and the Issuance of the NOPR .....
C. Summary of Changes to the PURPA Regulations Implemented by This Final Rule ...............................................................
IV. Discussion ...........................................................................................................................................................................................
A. General Legal Standards Under PURPA .....................................................................................................................................
1. Encouragement of QFs ...........................................................................................................................................................
a. Comments ........................................................................................................................................................................
b. Commission Determination ............................................................................................................................................
2. Discrimination ........................................................................................................................................................................
a. Comments ........................................................................................................................................................................
b. Commission Determination ............................................................................................................................................
3. Unlawful Delegation and the Role of Nonregulated Electric Utilities ...............................................................................
a. Comments ........................................................................................................................................................................
b. Commission Determination ............................................................................................................................................
B. QF Rates ........................................................................................................................................................................................
1. Overview ................................................................................................................................................................................
2. Use of Competitive Market Prices To Set As-Available Avoided Cost Rates ....................................................................
a. NOPR Proposal ................................................................................................................................................................
b. Comments ........................................................................................................................................................................
c. Commission Determination ............................................................................................................................................
3. LMP as a Permissible Rate for Certain As-Available Avoided Cost Rates .........................................................................
a. NOPR Proposal ................................................................................................................................................................
b. Comments ........................................................................................................................................................................
i. Comments in Opposition .........................................................................................................................................
(a) Utilizing Western EIM To Establish Avoided Costs ............................................................................................
ii. Comments in Support .............................................................................................................................................
(a) Utilizing Western EIM To Establish Avoided Costs ............................................................................................
iii. Comments in Support With Requested Modifications/Clarifications ................................................................
c. Commission Determination ............................................................................................................................................
i. Arguments Against the NOPR Proposal ..................................................................................................................
ii. Requests for Modification or Clarification of the NOPR ......................................................................................
iii. Western EIM ...........................................................................................................................................................
4. Use of Market Hub Prices as a Permissible Rate for Certain As-Available QF Energy Sales ...........................................
a. NOPR Proposal ................................................................................................................................................................
b. Comments ........................................................................................................................................................................
i. Comments in Support ..............................................................................................................................................
ii. Comments in Opposition ........................................................................................................................................
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
PO 00000
Frm 00002
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
1
5
6
13
17
18
20
28
35
39
42
47
47
51
56
67
67
68
68
70
79
79
82
89
89
93
96
96
103
104
107
114
124
124
129
129
137
138
145
146
151
155
173
177
180
180
182
182
184
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
54639
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
Paragraph
Nos.
iii. Commission Determination ...................................................................................................................................
c. Proposed Modifications ..................................................................................................................................................
i. Comments .................................................................................................................................................................
ii. Commission Determination ....................................................................................................................................
5. Use of Formulas Based on Natural Gas Prices To Establish a Permissible Rate for Certain As-Available QF Energy
Sales ........................................................................................................................................................................................
a. NOPR Proposal ................................................................................................................................................................
b. Comments ........................................................................................................................................................................
c. Commission Determination ............................................................................................................................................
6. Permitting the Energy Rate Component of a Contract To Be Fixed at the Time of the LEO Using Forecasted Values
of the Estimated Stream of Market Revenues .......................................................................................................................
a. Comments ........................................................................................................................................................................
b. Commission Determination ............................................................................................................................................
7. Providing for Variable Energy Rates in QF Contracts .........................................................................................................
a. Background ......................................................................................................................................................................
b. NOPR Proposal ...............................................................................................................................................................
c. General Comments on the NOPR Proposal ...................................................................................................................
i. Comments in Support of NOPR Proposal ...............................................................................................................
ii. Comments in Opposition to NOPR Proposal ........................................................................................................
iii. Commission Determination ...................................................................................................................................
d. Whether the Current Approach Has Resulted in Payments to QFs in Excess of Avoided Costs ..............................
i. Comments in Support of NOPR Proposal ...............................................................................................................
ii. Comments in Opposition to NOPR Proposal ........................................................................................................
iii. Commission Determination ...................................................................................................................................
e. Whether the Proposed Change Would Violate the Statutory Requirement That the PURPA Regulations Encourage QFs .............................................................................................................................................................................
i. Comments .................................................................................................................................................................
i. Commission Determination .....................................................................................................................................
f. Discrimination .................................................................................................................................................................
i. Comments in Support of NOPR Proposal ...............................................................................................................
ii. Comments in Opposition to NOPR Proposal ........................................................................................................
iii. Commission Determination ...................................................................................................................................
g. Effect of Variable Energy Rates on Financing ...............................................................................................................
i. Comments in Support of the NOPR Proposal ........................................................................................................
ii. Comments in Opposition to the NOPR Proposal ..................................................................................................
iii. Commission Determination ...................................................................................................................................
h. Other Claimed Benefits of Fixed Avoided Cost Energy Rates .....................................................................................
i. Comments .................................................................................................................................................................
ii. Commission Determination ....................................................................................................................................
i. Potential Modifications to NOPR Proposal ....................................................................................................................
i. Comments .................................................................................................................................................................
ii. Commission Determination ....................................................................................................................................
8. Consideration of Competitive Solicitations To Determine Avoided Costs ........................................................................
a. NOPR Proposal ................................................................................................................................................................
b. Comments ........................................................................................................................................................................
i. Comments in Opposition .........................................................................................................................................
ii. Comments in Support .............................................................................................................................................
iii. Comments Requesting Modifications/Clarifications ............................................................................................
(a) Requests for Clarification and/or Separate Proceedings ......................................................................................
(b) Requests Regarding Proposed Criteria ..................................................................................................................
(c) Other Requests ........................................................................................................................................................
c. Commission Determination ............................................................................................................................................
i. Requests for Clarification and/or Separate Proceedings ........................................................................................
ii. Proposed Criteria .....................................................................................................................................................
iii. Other Requests .......................................................................................................................................................
C. Relief from Purchase Obligation in Competitive Retail Markets ...............................................................................................
1. NOPR Proposal .......................................................................................................................................................................
2. Comments ...............................................................................................................................................................................
3. Commission Determination ...................................................................................................................................................
D. Evaluation of Whether QFs Are at Separate Sites ......................................................................................................................
1. Rebuttable Presumption of Separate Sites ............................................................................................................................
a. NOPR Proposal ................................................................................................................................................................
b. Commission Determination ............................................................................................................................................
c. Need for Reform ..............................................................................................................................................................
i. Comments .................................................................................................................................................................
ii. Commission Determination ....................................................................................................................................
d. Site Definition .................................................................................................................................................................
i. Comments .................................................................................................................................................................
ii. Commission Determination ....................................................................................................................................
e. Distance Between Facilities ............................................................................................................................................
i. Comments .................................................................................................................................................................
ii. Commission Determination ....................................................................................................................................
f. Factors ..............................................................................................................................................................................
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
PO 00000
Frm 00003
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
189
195
195
200
203
203
206
211
217
219
227
232
232
234
245
245
248
253
265
265
272
283
294
294
295
297
297
298
302
304
304
312
335
350
350
351
354
354
357
361
361
368
368
375
383
383
390
400
411
415
420
439
442
442
444
456
458
458
458
466
470
470
472
473
473
476
482
482
490
497
54640
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
Paragraph
Nos.
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
i. Comments .................................................................................................................................................................
ii. Commission Determination ....................................................................................................................................
g. Exemptions ......................................................................................................................................................................
i. Comments .................................................................................................................................................................
ii. Commission Determination ....................................................................................................................................
2. Electrical Generating Equipment ..........................................................................................................................................
a. NOPR Proposal ................................................................................................................................................................
b. Comments ........................................................................................................................................................................
c. Commission Determination ............................................................................................................................................
E. QF Certification Process ...............................................................................................................................................................
1. NOPR Proposal .......................................................................................................................................................................
2. Comments ...............................................................................................................................................................................
3. Commission Determination ...................................................................................................................................................
F. Corresponding Changes to the FERC Form No. 556 ...................................................................................................................
1. NOPR Proposal .......................................................................................................................................................................
2. Comments ...............................................................................................................................................................................
3. Commission Determination ...................................................................................................................................................
G. PURPA Section 210(m) Rebuttable Presumption of Nondiscriminatory Access to Markets ...................................................
1. PURPA Section 210(m) Implementation ..............................................................................................................................
a. NOPR Proposal ................................................................................................................................................................
b. Comments in Opposition ...............................................................................................................................................
i. Insufficient Evidentiary Support .............................................................................................................................
ii. Administrative Burden and Complex Market Rules .............................................................................................
c. Comments in Support .....................................................................................................................................................
d. Comments Requesting Modifications/Clarifications ....................................................................................................
e. Commission Determination ............................................................................................................................................
2. Reliance on RFPs and Liquid Market Hubs To Terminate Purchase Obligation Under PURPA Section 210(m) ...........
a. NOPR Discussion ............................................................................................................................................................
b. Comments ........................................................................................................................................................................
i. Comments in Opposition .........................................................................................................................................
ii. Comments in Support .............................................................................................................................................
c. Commission Determination ............................................................................................................................................
H. Legally Enforceable Obligation ....................................................................................................................................................
1. NOPR Proposal .......................................................................................................................................................................
2. Comments ...............................................................................................................................................................................
a. Comments in Opposition ................................................................................................................................................
b. Comments in Support ....................................................................................................................................................
c. Comments Requesting Modification ..............................................................................................................................
i. Studies ......................................................................................................................................................................
ii. Commercial Viability ..............................................................................................................................................
iii. Financial Viability .................................................................................................................................................
iv. Rejecting QF Purchases and Expanded Curtailment Rights ................................................................................
3. Commission Determination ...................................................................................................................................................
V. Information Collection Statement .......................................................................................................................................................
VI. Environmental Analysis .....................................................................................................................................................................
A. Comments .....................................................................................................................................................................................
B. Commission Determination ..........................................................................................................................................................
1. No EIS or EA is Required ......................................................................................................................................................
a. There Is No Project That Defines the Scope and Limits of QF Development ............................................................
b. A Categorical Exclusion Applies ...................................................................................................................................
i. Changes That Are Clarifying in Nature ...................................................................................................................
ii. Changes That Are Corrective in Nature .................................................................................................................
iii. Changes That Are Procedural in Nature ...............................................................................................................
2. The NEPA Analysis for Promulgation of the Original PURPA Regulations in 1980 Cannot Be Replicated Here ..........
3. This Proceeding Does Not Trigger Any ESA Consultation Requirement ...........................................................................
VII. Regulatory Flexibility Act Certification ...........................................................................................................................................
VIII. Document Availability .....................................................................................................................................................................
IX. Effective Dates and Congressional Notification ................................................................................................................................
I. Introduction
1. In this Order, the Federal Energy
Regulatory Commission (Commission)
issues its final rule approving certain
revisions to its regulations (PURPA
Regulations) 1 implementing sections
201 and 210 of the Public Utility
Regulatory Policies Act of 1978
(PURPA).2
2. On September 19, 2019, the
Commission issued a notice of proposed
rulemaking (NOPR) proposing to modify
its PURPA Regulations.3 Those
2 16
1 18
CFR part 292 (2019). In connection with the
revisions to the PURPA Regulations, the
Commission also is revising its delegation of
authority to Commission staff in 18 CFR pt. 375.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
U.S.C. 796(17)–(18), 824a–3.
Facility Rates and Requirements
Implementation Issues Under the Public Utility
Regulatory Policies Act of 1978, 168 FERC ¶ 61184
(2019) (NOPR).
3 Qualifying
PO 00000
Frm 00004
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
497
508
512
512
514
515
515
518
521
525
525
530
547
570
570
577
584
597
597
597
602
603
611
614
617
624
648
648
651
651
655
659
663
663
666
666
673
676
677
679
681
683
684
697
702
703
710
712
712
720
721
722
727
728
737
743
750
753
regulations were promulgated in 1980
and have been modified in only specific
respects since then. Approximately 130
separate comments were submitted in
response to the NOPR,4 several of which
were submitted on behalf of multiple
parties. In total, over 1,600 pages of
comments were submitted, and in
addition thousands of pages of exhibits
4 See
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
Appendix for list of commenters.
02SER2
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
were attached to the comments. The
entities that filed comments are listed in
Appendix A. This final rule addresses
comments received in response to the
NOPR.
3. We largely adopt the NOPR
proposals. However, this final rule
makes certain modifications to the
NOPR proposals, as further discussed
below.
4. Given the Commission’s expressed
intent in the NOPR to propose revisions
to the PURPA Regulations that more
closely adhere to the goals and terms of
PURPA,5 we considered comments
regarding whether these proposals are
consistent with the requirements of
PURPA. Based on that review and
further consideration, we adopt the
following changes to the proposals in
the NOPR, among certain others
described below:
• We establish a rebuttable
presumption, rather than a per se rule,
that locational marginal prices (LMPs)
may reflect a purchasing electric
utility’s avoided energy costs;
• We provide that any competitive
solicitations used to establish avoided
capacity costs must adhere to the
Commission’s Allegheny 6 standard for
evaluating competitive solicitations;
• We do not adopt the proposed rule
permitting states with retail competition
to allow relief from the purchase
obligation but instead clarify that the
Commission’s existing PURPA
Regulations already require that states,
to the extent practicable, must account
for reduced loads in setting QF capacity
rates;
• We clarify terminology we used in
the NOPR relating to the determination
of whether small power production
facilities are separate facilities to focus
not on whether they are separate
facilities, but rather to mirror the
statutory language and thus focus on
whether they are at ‘‘the same site’’;
• We clarify in the regulations that
protests may be made to initial selfcertifications and applications for
Commission certification, but only to
self-recertifications and applications for
Commission recertification making
substantive changes to the existing
certification;
• We identify additional factors that
can be considered for small power
production qualifying facilities (QFs)
located more than one but less than 10
miles apart, such as evidence of shared
control systems, common permitting
and land leasing, and shared step-up
transformers;
5 NOPR,
168 FERC ¶ 61,184 at P 31.
Energy Supply Co., LLC, 108 FERC
¶ 61,082, at P 18 (2004) (Allegheny).
6 Allegheny
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
• We revise the regulations to lower
the rebuttable presumption of small
power production QFs’
nondiscriminatory access to 5 MW,
rather than 1 MW as proposed in the
NOPR, and include factors that a small
power production QF sized greater than
5 MW could rely on to rebut the
presumption that it has
nondiscriminatory access to markets
defined in PURPA sections 210(m)(1);
and
• We revise the proposed
requirements to establish a legally
enforceable obligation (LEO) to provide
that with regard to the issue of obtaining
permits, QFs need only have applied for
all required permits, instead of being
required to have already obtained those
permits.
II. Overview
5. Before discussing each of the
individual changes to the PURPA
Regulations adopted herein, this final
rule first addresses certain overall
themes raised in the comments on the
NOPR, both those supporting the NOPR
and those opposing.
A. The Commission’s PURPA
Regulations, as Revised by This Final
Rule, Continue To Encourage the
Development of QFs Within the
Requirements of PURPA’s Statutory
Limitations
6. PURPA section 210(a) requires that
the Commission prescribe rules that it
determines necessary to encourage the
development of qualifying small power
production facilities and cogeneration
facilities.
7. The bulk of the criticism of the
Commission’s proposed rule changes is
based on a widespread
misunderstanding, as reflected in the
comments on the NOPR, that PURPA
and the PURPA Regulations were
intended to encourage QF development
without any limit, and that the rule
changes proposed in the NOPR
improperly reduce or even eliminate
encouragement in contravention of the
statute. Those commenters opposing the
NOPR proposals argue that the
Commission has determined, in
contravention of the statute, that there
no longer is a need to encourage QFs,
or eliminated any provision that
provides such encouragement.7 Many of
the commenters supporting the changes
7 See, e.g., Biological Diversity Comments at 14;
ConEd Development Comments at 2; Harvard
Electricity Law Comments at 4; New England Small
Hydro Comments at 4; NIPPC, CREIA, REC, and
OSEIA Comments at 3, 21, 28; Public Interest
Organizations Comments at 9, 39; Solar Energy
Industries Comments at 4; Southeast Public Interest
Organizations Comments at 17.
PO 00000
Frm 00005
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
54641
proposed in the NOPR applaud the
Commission for eliminating what they
argue amounts to an improper subsidy
of QFs.8
8. Neither side is correct about either
what PURPA and the current PURPA
Regulations require, or the basis for the
changes to the PURPA Regulations
proposed in the NOPR.
9. As an initial matter, PURPA was
not a directive to the Commission to
encourage QF development without
limitation. Indeed, as explained below,
Congress included several limitations in
PURPA. By reading the statute as a
whole, and the PURPA Regulations as a
whole as revised by this final rule, it is
clear that the PURPA Regulations
continue to encourage the development
of QFs consistent with PURPA.9
10. We also emphasize that we do not
by this final rule change other elements
to the Commission’s existing PURPA
Regulations that continue to encourage
QF development. These elements
include, but are not limited to, rules
that: (1) Require electric utilities to
provide backup electric energy to QFs
on a non-discriminatory basis and at
just and reasonable rates; (2) require
electric utilities to interconnect with
QFs; and (3) provide exemptions to QFs
from many provisions of the Federal
Power Act (FPA) and state laws
governing utility rates and financial
organization.10 These provisions
encourage the development of QFs by
relieving them of certain regulatory
burdens otherwise imposed on sellers of
power and ensure they can operate their
facilities. Moreover, we stress that,
besides the changes to the PURPA
Regulations regarding applications to
terminate a purchasing electric utility’s
mandatory purchase obligation under
PURPA section 210(m) (see infra section
IV.G), nothing in this final rule
eliminates QFs’ rights to sell electric
energy or capacity as provided under
PURPA.
11. As discussed in greater detail
below, while PURPA provided for the
encouragement of cogeneration and
small power production, PURPA also
provided that the Commission could not
prescribe a rule that provided for ‘‘a rate
which exceeds the incremental cost to
the electric utility of alternative electric
energy.’’ 11 Furthermore, PURPA
requires the Commission to ‘‘insure’’
that the resulting rates ‘‘shall be just and
reasonable to the electric consumers of
8 See Competitive Enterprise Institute Comments
at 3; Progressive Policy Institute Comments at 1–2;
SBE Council Comments at 2; Mr. Moore Comments
at 1–2.
9 16 U.S.C. 824a–3(a).
10 See 18 CFR 292.303(c), 292.305, 292.601–02.
11 Compare id. with 16 U.S.C. 824a–3(b).
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
54642
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
the electric utility and in the public
interest[.]’’ 12 Likewise, while PURPA
provided for the encouragement of small
power production, PURPA also limited
the facilities which could be encouraged
to those facilities with no more than 80
MW power production capacity at the
same site.13
12. Nothing in the text of PURPA
requires the establishment of a subsidy
for QFs. This point was confirmed in
the Conference Report accompanying
PURPA’s passage: ‘‘The provisions of
this section are not intended to require
the rate payers of a utility to subsidize
cogenerators or small power
producers.’’ 14 Congress thus structured
PURPA both specifically to give effect to
its intent that QFs not be subsidized and
also to impose other mandatory limits
on the Commission’s ability to
encourage QFs that are relevant to this
final rule, as briefly summarized below.
1. Avoided Cost Cap on QF Rates
13. PURPA section 210(b) sets out the
standards governing the rates
purchasing utilities must pay to QFs.15
Sections 210(b)(1) and (b)(2) provide
that QF rates ‘‘shall be just and
reasonable to the electric consumers of
the electric utility and in the public
interest’’ and ‘‘shall not discriminate
against qualifying cogenerators or
qualifying small power producers.’’ 16
After establishing these standards,
Congress then placed, in the final
sentence of section 210(b), a cap on the
level of the rates utilities could be
required to pay QFs: ‘‘No such rule
prescribed under subsection (a) shall
provide for a rate which exceeds the
incremental cost to the electric utility of
alternative electric energy.’’ 17 As the
Conference Report for PURPA explains:
[T]he utility would not be required to
purchase electric energy from a qualifying
cogeneration or small power production
facility at a rate which exceeds the lower of
the rate described above, namely a rate which
is just and reasonable to consumers of the
utility, in the public interest, and
nondiscriminatory, or the incremental cost of
alternate electric energy. This limitation on
the rates which may be required in
12 16
U.S.C. 824a–3(b)(1).
16 U.S.C. 824a–3(a) with 16 U.S.C.
796(17)(A)(ii).
14 H.R. Rep. No. 95–1750, at 98 (1978) (Conf.
Rep.).
15 16 U.S.C. 824a–3(b).
16 Id.
17 Id. (emphasis added). The statute defines an
electric utility’s ‘‘incremental costs’’ as ‘‘the cost to
the electric utility of the electric energy which, but
for the purchase from such cogenerator or small
power producer, such utility would generate or
purchase from another source.’’ 16 U.S.C. 824a–
3(d); see also 18 CFR 292.101(b)(6) (implementing
same and defining such ‘‘incremental costs’’ as
‘‘avoided costs’’).
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
13 Compare
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
purchasing from a cogenerator or small
power producer is meant to act as an upper
limit on the price at which utilities can be
required under this section to purchase
electric energy.18
14. This upper limit on QF rates
established in section 210(b), equal to a
purchasing utility’s incremental costs,
commonly called ‘‘avoided costs,’’
implements Congress’s intent that QFs
not be subsidized. It ensures that the
purchasing utility cannot be required to
pay more for power purchased from a
QF than it would otherwise pay to
generate the power itself or to purchase
power from a third party.
15. Consistent with the statutory
standard, when the Commission issued
its PURPA Regulations in 1980, it set
the rates for QFs at, but not above, the
statutorily defined incremental or
avoided cost of alternative electric
energy.19 The PURPA Regulations
applied this limitation generally to QF
rates, without distinguishing between
as-available energy 20 and the fixed
energy and capacity rate option
applicable to long-term contracts or
other legally enforceable obligations.21
In either case, though, the PURPA
Regulations essentially capped the rate
paid to QFs at the purchasing electric
utility’s avoided costs.22
16. Order No. 69, in which the
Commission promulgated the PURPA
Regulations,23 makes clear that the
Commission also recognized that
allowing the option for a fixed energy
and capacity rate option for long-term
contracts or other legally enforceable
obligations could result in a rate that, at
times, exceeded incremental or avoided
18 Conf.
Rep. at 98 (emphasis added).
16 U.S.C. 824a–3(b) & (d) with 18 CFR
292.101(b)(6), 292.304(a)(2) & (b)(2).
20 18 CFR 292.304(d)(1).
21 18 CFR 292.304(d)(2) (providing QFs the right
to elect avoided costs calculated at the time of
delivery or avoided costs calculated at the time the
obligation is incurred). In this final rule, we refer
to the QF’s option for avoided costs calculated at
the time the obligation is incurred as the fixed
energy and capacity rate option. 18 CFR
292.304(d)(2).
22 The regulations, however, also allowed both for
negotiated rates that differed from the rates that
would otherwise be applicable, see 18 CFR
292.301(b), and for rates to be set based on
estimates of avoided costs even though such rates
might differ from avoided costs at the time of
delivery. See 18 CFR 292.304(b)(5).
23 Small Power Production and Cogeneration
Facilities; Regulations Implementing Section 210 of
the Public Utility Regulatory Policies Act of 1978,
Order No. 69, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 30,128, at
30,880 (cross-referenced 10 FERC ¶ 61,150), order
on reh’g, Order No. 69–A, FERC Stats. & Regs.
¶ 30,160 (1980) (cross-referenced at 11 FERC
¶ 61,166), aff’d in part & vacated in part sub nom.
Am. Elec. Power Serv. Corp. v. FERC, 675 F.2d 1226
(D.C. Cir. 1982), rev’d in part sub nom. Am. Paper
Inst., Inc. v. Am. Elec. Power Serv. Corp., 461 U.S.
402 (1983) (API).
19 Compare
PO 00000
Frm 00006
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
cost of alternative electric energy. The
Commission acknowledged in this
regard that some commenters had
asserted that, ‘‘if the avoided cost of
energy at the time it is supplied is less
than the price provided in the contract
or obligation, the purchasing utility
would be required to pay a rate for
purchases that would subsidize the
qualifying facility at the expense of the
utility’s other ratepayers.’’ 24 In
response, the Commission stated that it
‘‘recognize[d] this possibility, but is
cognizant that in other cases, the
required rate will turn out to be lower
than the avoided cost at the time of
purchase.’’ 25 The Commission
concluded that any over- and underrecoveries compared to avoided cost
‘‘will balance out’’ and, based on this
conclusion, found that the fixed energy
and capacity rate option applicable to
long-term contracts or other legally
enforceable obligations did not violate
the statutory cap.26 But, to be clear, the
option the Commission implemented in
1980 was not based on any
determination by the Commission that
the rates in QF contracts may routinely
exceed avoided costs in the ordinary
course of events in order to encourage
QFs.
2. Limitation on Small Power
Production Facilities Located at the
Same ‘‘Site’’
17. Another way in which Congress
set boundaries on the Commission’s
ability to encourage development of QFs
was to define small power production
facilities, one of the categories of
generators that under the statute is to be
encouraged. The definition of small
power production facilities applies to
almost all renewable resources that wish
to be QFs, requiring that those facilities
have ‘‘a power production capacity
which, together with any other facilities
located at the same site (as determined
by the Commission), is not greater than
80 megawatts.’’ 27 In order to comply
with this statutory requirement that the
capacity of all small power production
facilities ‘‘located at the same site’’
cannot exceed 80 MW, the Commission
is required to define what constitutes a
‘‘site.’’ The Commission determined in
1980 that, essentially, those facilities
that are owned by the same or affiliated
entities and using the same energy
resource should be deemed to be at the
same site ‘‘if they are located within one
mile of the facility for which
24 Order No. 69, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 30,128 at
30,880.
25 Id.
26 Id.
27 16 U.S.C. 796(17)(A)(ii).
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
qualification is sought.’’ 28 This
definition, known as the ‘‘one-mile
rule,’’ interpreted Congress’s limitation
of 80 MW located at the same site to
apply to just those affiliated small
power production qualifying facilities
located within one mile of each other.
3. Termination of Purchase Obligation
for QFs With Nondiscriminatory Access
to Certain Competitive Markets
18. Finally, Congress amended
PURPA in 2005 to further limit the
statute. Congress amended PURPA
section 210 to add section 210(m),
which provides for termination of the
requirement that an electric utility enter
into a new obligation or contract to
purchase from a QF if the QF has
nondiscriminatory access to certain
defined types of markets.29 This
amendment reflected Congress’s
judgment that non-discriminatory
access to these markets provided
adequate encouragement for those QFs.
19. Congress directed the Commission
to implement this requirement, which it
did in Order No. 688. In that order, the
Commission identified certain markets
in which utilities would no longer be
subject to the PURPA mandatory
purchase obligation under PURPA
section 210(m) because certain QFs have
nondiscriminatory access to such
markets.30 Although not required in the
new PURPA section 210(m), the
Commission established a rebuttable
presumption that a QF with a net power
production capacity at or below 20 MW
does not have nondiscriminatory access
to such markets.31 In creating this
rebuttable presumption, the
Commission found persuasive
arguments that some QFs may not have
nondiscriminatory access to markets in
light of their small size.
4. Final Rule’s Updating of the PURPA
Regulations
20. In this final rule, we are amending
the PURPA Regulations, principally
with regard to the three statutory
provisions described above, i.e.: (1) The
avoided cost cap on QF rates; (2) the 80
MW limitation applicable to the
combined capacity of affiliated small
power production QFs located at the
same site; and (3) the termination of the
mandatory purchase obligation for QFs
28 18
CFR 292.204(a)(ii).
16 U.S.C. 824a–3(m).
30 New PURPA Section 210(m) Regulations
Applicable to Small Power Production and
Cogeneration Facilities, Order No. 688, 117 FERC
¶ 61,078, at PP 9–12 (2006), order on reh’g, Order
No. 688–A, 119 FERC ¶ 61,305 (2007), aff’d sub
nom. Am. Forest & Paper Ass’n v. FERC, 550 F.3d
1179 (D.C. Cir. 2008).
31 18 CFR 292.309(d)(1).
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
29 See
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
54643
with nondiscriminatory access to
certain markets. Contrary to
commenters’ assertions that the
Commission has determined that it no
longer is necessary to encourage QFs
and therefore that the Commission is
making these changes in an
impermissible attempt to undo
PURPA,32 we are modifying the PURPA
Regulations based on demonstrated
changes in circumstances since the
current PURPA Regulations were first
adopted to ensure that the regulations
continue to comply with PURPA’s
statutory requirements established by
Congress.
21. For example, as explained in more
detail below, the Commission’s
expectation expressed in 1980 that overand under-recovery in rates compared to
avoided cost ‘‘will balance out’’ 33 was
critical to the Commission’s
determination in 1980 that the fixed
energy and capacity rate option
applicable to long-term contracts or
other legally enforceable obligations did
not violate the statutory avoided cost
cap on QF rates. However, record
evidence now demonstrates that this
expectation no longer is necessarily
accurate. The Commission’s change to
the PURPA Regulations adopted in this
final rule, giving states the ability to
require variable energy rates in longterm contracts or other legally
enforceable obligations, allows the
states to better ensure that QF rates are
at, but do not exceed, the statutory
maximum rate established by Congress.
22. This change is important for
purposes of compliance with PURPA’s
statutory mandates. As explained below,
setting QF rates at avoided costs allows
the Commission to comply with the
statutory goals of encouraging QFs and
providing for nondiscriminatory rates
while at the same time ensuring that
such rates are just and reasonable to
consumers and do not subsidize QFs.
The record shows that on some
occasions long-term fixed QF rates were
well above actual avoided costs, thereby
causing consumers to subsidize those
QFs in contravention of PURPA and the
Commission’s expectations.
23. Similarly, the changes
implemented by the Commission in this
final rule to the one-mile rule are
intended to better ensure compliance
with the statutory requirement that
small power production facilities
located at the same site cannot exceed
80 MW. And, 15 years after Congress
added PURPA section 210(m), because
the Commission can now make the
determination, described below, that
smaller QFs have non-discriminatory
access to RTO/ISO markets, an update
to the rebuttable presumption regarding
non-discriminatory access to those
markets is appropriate to better ensure
compliance with the statute.
24. Some commenters incorrectly
assert that the final rule impermissibly
revises the PURPA Regulations in a way
that no longer encourages QFs. PURPA
section 210(a) provides not simply that
the Commission is to prescribe rules
that encourage QFs, but rather that the
Commission is to ‘‘prescribe, and from
time to time thereafter revise, such rules
as it determines necessary to encourage’’
QFs. Carrying out Congress’s directive
to ‘‘from time to time thereafter revise’’
the rules is at the heart of what the
Commission is doing in this final rule.
Consistent with this directive, the
Commission is considering revisions to
‘‘such rules as it determines necessary
to’’ encourage QFs in light of current
industry circumstances.34
25. The changes adopted in this final
rule result from the need for the PURPA
Regulations to continue to comply with
the directives Congress established
when it enacted PURPA in 1978, and
then again when Congress amended
PURPA in 2005. These changes are not
based on any determination by the
Commission that the encouragement
directed by PURPA is no longer needed.
The question of whether QFs should
continue to be encouraged or not
remains a question for Congress.
26. Moreover, PURPA also requires
the Commission to insure that the rates
for QF purchases be ‘‘just and
reasonable to the electric consumers of
the electric utility and in the public
interest[.]’’ 35 The obligation to
encourage is also limited by the
requirement that, ‘‘No such rule
prescribed under subsection (a) [the
encouragement provision] shall provide
for a rate which exceeds the incremental
cost to the electric utility of alternative
electric energy.’’ 36
27. We recognize that some of the
comments opposing the NOPR may
32 Biomass Power Comments at 2; Biological
Diversity at 12; EPSA Comments at 6 (‘‘[T]he NOPR
changes ‘would effectively gut’ PURPA.’’); NIPPC,
CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 28–29; Public
Interest Groups Comments at 25 (‘‘[T]he changes
proposed in the NOPR will gut PURPA-mandated
measures to encourage QF development.’’); Solar
Energy Industries Comments at 8–14.
33 Order No. 69, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 30,128 at
30,880.
34 We view the revisions to our rules
implementing PURPA that we adopt in this final
rule as consistent with Congress’s explicit directive
that the Commission ‘‘from time to time thereafter
[to] revise’’ the rules. We do not view Congress as
intending that the Commission only ever consider
the circumstances that existed in the late 1970s and
not current circumstances, 40 years later.
35 16 U.S.C. 824a–3(b).
36 16 U.S.C. 824a–3(b).
PO 00000
Frm 00007
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
54644
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
have been influenced by the
Commission’s recitation in the
Background section of the NOPR of the
broad changes in circumstances since
the PURPA Regulations were first
promulgated 40 years ago, including the
discovery of significant new natural gas
reserves, the evolution of the electric
industry to include a significant
independent power presence, the
establishment of organized competitive
markets, and the advances in renewable
energy technologies.37 We clarify that
the Commission referenced this general
background information in the NOPR
primarily to explain why it decided to
re-evaluate its PURPA Regulations at all
and as Congress said we should, and not
necessarily to support the individual
proposals included in the NOPR. The
facts we rely on to propose specific
changes, which include some, but not
all, of those background facts, were
cited in the specific sections of the
NOPR describing those proposed
changes. And the facts on which we rely
to promulgate the specific changes in
this final rule again are cited in the
specific sections describing those
changes.
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
B. The Final Rule Ensures That the
Commission’s Implementation of
PURPA Continues To Benefit QFs,
Purchasing Electric Utilities, and
Electric Consumers
28. The final rule implements
additional changes consistent with
PURPA that also are designed to benefit
QFs, purchasing utilities, and electric
consumers. The changes to the PURPA
Regulations adopted in this final rule
will enable the Commission to continue
satisfying the statutory requirement that
the Commission promulgate rules to
encourage QF development consistent
with PURPA’s requirements. Claims to
the contrary by commenters to the effect
that the ‘‘proposals are uniformly biased
against QF development’’ 38 have no
merit.
29. As an initial matter, we are not
changing the determination in the
PURPA Regulations that QF rates must
equal a purchasing electric utility’s full
avoided costs.39 As the Supreme Court
noted in API, the full avoided cost rate
requirement represents the maximum
rate permitted under PURPA, and
thereby provides important
encouragement to QFs.40 The Court
37 NOPR,
168 FERC ¶ 61,184, at PP 15–27.
Electricity Law Comments at 1.
39 See 18 CFR 292.304(b)(2); NOPR, 168 FERC
¶ 61,184 at P 34.
40 API, 461 U.S. at 413. PURPA does not use the
terms ‘‘avoided cost’’ or ‘‘full avoided cost’’; rather,
PURPA uses the term ‘‘incremental cost of
alternative electric energy.’’ The Commission’s
38 Harvard
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
explained that the full avoided cost rate
requirement encourages QF
development because QFs ‘‘retain an
incentive to produce energy under the
full-avoided-cost rule so long as their
marginal costs did not exceed the full
avoided cost of the purchasing
utility.’’ 41
30. In addition, several of the changes
to the current PURPA Regulations
implemented by this final rule are based
expressly on a finding that they are
beneficial to QFs as well as to
purchasing utilities and ratepayers. For
example, the provisions of the final rule
allowing for energy rates to be based on
transparent, competitive market
prices—in appropriate circumstances—
are supported by comments submitted
at the Technical Conference, where
representatives of QFs and utilities both
expressed a preference for transparent
prices for QFs.42 This conclusion is
supported by the Fitch Report, cited by
NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA,
explaining how Fitch evaluates the
financial strength of renewable energy
projects. In this report, Fitch states that
it gives a ‘‘stronger’’ evaluation to
projects with power sales contract
prices that are ‘‘indexed using simple,
broad-based publicly available
indexation formulas.’’ 43
31. Setting prices that are indexed
using simple, broad-based publicly
available formulas is precisely what the
Commission’s changes permitting
reference to competitive market prices
will achieve. Such prices reflect avoided
costs in a simpler, more transparent,
and predictable manner than through an
administrative process, which should
encourage the development of QFs
while at the same time providing
benefits to utilities and consumers.
regulations and subsequent decisions have used the
term ‘‘avoided cost’’ to explain the Commission’s
application of the ‘‘incremental cost’’ standard. The
API decision and early Commission precedents
referred to ‘‘full’’ avoided costs to distinguish
between the Commission’s decision to set QF rates
at avoided costs and proposals from certain parties
that rates be set at something less than avoided
costs. We continue to use the terms avoided costs
and full avoided costs as being consistent with the
statutory term incremental cost.
41 Id. at 416.
42 See American Forest & Paper Association,
Comments, Docket No. AD16–16–000, at 8 (filed
June 8, 2016) (‘‘To the extent possible, these
determinations [of avoided costs] should not be
made in a ‘black box’, but rather, as part of an open
and transparent method and process.’’); Edison
Electric Institute (EEI) Comments, Docket No.
AD16–16–000, at 3 (filed June 30, 2016) (‘‘Where
transparent competitive markets with day ahead
prices exist, there is no reason to adhere to secondbest avoided cost pricing mechanisms.’’).
43 NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at
37–38 (citing FitchRatings, Global Infrastructure &
Project Finance, Renewable Energy Project Rating
Criteria,’’ at 3 (Feb. 26, 2019), https://
www.fitchratings.com/site/re/10061770).
PO 00000
Frm 00008
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
Using transparent market prices to
establish as-available avoided cost rates
also allows QFs, utilities, and the states
to avoid the expenditure of the time and
resources involved in litigating
administratively-set avoided cost rates,
and allows those rates to automatically
adjust—up and down—as avoided costs
change.
32. Similarly, the provisions regarding
competitive solicitations adopted herein
were added at the suggestion of both
NARUC and certain developers of
renewable resource QFs, such as Solar
Energy Industries. These competitive
solicitations can provide a fair and
transparent method for QFs to establish
full avoided cost rates. As Solar Energy
Industries stated in its comments,
‘‘[c]ompetitive solicitations, with
adequate safeguards, can deliver
substantial value.’’ 44 Competitive
solicitations may be an especially
appropriate tool in those regions outside
of Regional Transmission Organizations
(RTOs) and Independent System
Operators (ISOs) where there are no
organized competitive markets where
QFs can make sales.
33. Likewise, the LEO provisions
adopted herein provide important
benefits to QFs. Under the current
PURPA Regulations, a LEO gives QFs
the enforceable right to require utilities
to purchase the QFs’ power at avoided
cost rates.45 This is an important right
that contributes to a QF owner’s ability
to obtain financing, especially the
development financing needed to
engage in the activities necessary to
subsequently obtain construction and
permanent financing. However, the
PURPA Regulations are silent as to
when and how a LEO is established,
which can leave QFs uncertain as to
when this key right has been
established. By providing more specific
guidance as to when a LEO is
established, the new rule creates greater
certainty for QFs (and utilities) on this
important element of QF development.
44 Solar Energy Industries Comments at 38. Solar
Energy Industries agreed that the competitive
solicitation provisions proposed in the NOPR ‘‘set
forth many important safeguards,’’ but
recommended that additional safeguards be
implemented. Those comments are discussed
below, and we have specifically adopted Solar
Energy Industries request made earlier in this
proceeding that all competitive solicitations must
be conducted pursuant to the Commission’s
Allegheny standard. See Solar Energy Industries
Supplemental Comments, Docket No. AD16–16–
000, at 32–34 (filed Aug. 28, 2019).
45 See 18 CFR 292.304(d)(2). Although the final
rule gives states the flexibility to require that energy
rates vary over the term of the LEO and be
calculated at the time of delivery, the final rule
retains the QF’s option to choose a fixed capacity
rate calculated at the time the LEO is established.
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
34. Some commenters assert that the
guidance provided by the Commission
may make it more difficult to obtain a
LEO.46 Their specific concerns are
discussed in detail below. But what
those commenters ignore is that, by
establishing objective and reasonable
state-determined criteria limited to
demonstrating commercial viability and
financial commitment, we also are
protecting QFs against onerous
requirements for a LEO that hinder
financing, such as a requirement for a
utility’s execution of an interconnection
agreement 47 or power purchase
agreement,48 or requiring that QFs file a
formal complaint with the state
commission,49 or limiting LEOs to only
those QFs capable of supplying firm
power,50 or requiring the QF to be able
to deliver power in 90 days.51 By
making clear in the PURPA Regulations
that such conditions are not permitted,
but describing which prerequisites a
state may impose to establish a LEO to
determine which QFs are commercially
viable and financially committed, we
are providing objective criteria to clarify
46 See NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments
at 81 (‘‘[A]ny requirement to demonstrate financing
to create a LEO violates the fundamental rule that
the utility’s actions should not be allowed to deny
the QF a LEO because the utility could prevent
creation of a LEO simply by refusing to sign the
PPA needed to secure such financing.’’); Public
Interest Organizations Comments at 98 (‘‘[T]he
Commission’s proposal to require QFs to
demonstrate commercial viability in order to obtain
a LEO will prevent many QFs from ever attaining
commercial viability at all. Creating a new
administrative obstacle to QF financing in this way
flies in the face of PURPA’s mandate to reduce
barriers to QF development.’’); Solar Energy
Industries Comments at 41 (‘‘Establishing higher
barriers to a determination of ‘commercial viability’
will only lead QF developers to invest additional
development capital and will simply weed out
those smaller companies that choose not to, or are
unable to, invest heavily in early-stage development
activity before an avoided cost rate is known. It is
unjust and unreasonable to cause QFs to invest tens
of millions of dollars in site control, permit
acquisition, interconnection, and other
development costs simply to secure the opportunity
to negotiate with the purchasing utility for a
contractual commitment.’’); Southeast Public
Interest Organizations Comments at 41 (describing
proposal as ‘‘discourag[ing] QF development since
achieving some of the indicia suggested by the
Commission often circularly requires that QF
developers have already obtained financing’’).
47 See, e.g., FLS Energy, Inc., 157 FERC ¶ 61,211,
at P 26 (2016) (FLS) (stating that requiring signed
interconnection agreement as prerequisite to LEO is
inconsistent with PURPA Regulations).
48 See, e.g., Murphy Flat Power, LLC, 141 FERC
¶ 61,145, at P 24 (2012) (finding that requiring a
signed and executed contract with an electric utility
as a prerequisite to a LEO is inconsistent with
PURPA Regulations.
49 See, e.g., Grouse Creek Wind Park, LLC, 142
FERC ¶ 61,187, at P 40 (2013).
50 Exelon Wind 1, L.L.C. v. Nelson, 766 F.3d 380,
400 (5th Cir. 2014).
51 Power Resource Group, Inc. v. Public Utility
Comm’n of Texas, 422 F.3d 231, (5th Cir. 2005).
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
when a LEO commences, which we find
will encourage the development of QFs.
C. The Commission Is Not Eliminating
Fixed Rate Pricing for QFs, But Rather
Is Giving States the Flexibility To
Require the Same Variable Energy Rate/
Fixed Capacity Rate Construct That
Applies Throughout the Electric
Industry
35. Another misconception reflected
in several comments is that the
Commission proposed in the NOPR to
eliminate fixed rate pricing for QFs.
Commenters argue that QFs cannot
obtain financing without fixed rates,
and from this they claim that the
proposal to give states the flexibility to
require variable energy rates would have
a devastating effect on future QF
development.52
36. This assertion that the
Commission has eliminated fixed rates
for QFs is not correct. The NOPR
proposal (which we adopt in this final
rule) gave states the flexibility, should
they choose to take advantage of this
flexibility, to require that the avoided
cost energy rates in QF contracts must
vary depending on avoided costs at the
time of delivery (rather than being fixed
at the time a LEO is incurred). The
NOPR thus made clear: ‘‘Under the
proposed revisions to § 292.304(d), a QF
would continue to be entitled to a
contract with avoided capacity costs
calculated and fixed at the time the LEO
is incurred.’’ 53 We are retaining in this
final rule the option granted to QFs to
fix their capacity rates for the term of
their contracts at the time the LEO is
incurred.
37. The fact that we are giving states
the flexibility to either require QF
contracts to have fixed capacity and
variable energy rates or to continue as
before to provide QFs the option of
fixed capacity and fixed energy rates—
has important consequences for the
ability of QF owners to finance their
projects. The energy rates of purchasing
electric utilities, upon which avoided
cost energy rates would be based,
typically reflect mainly the variable
costs of producing energy, such as the
cost of fuel and variable operations and
maintenance (O&M), especially for a
fossil fuel generator. Meanwhile, a
purchasing electric utility’s capacity
rates, upon which avoided cost capacity
rates would be based, tend to reflect
fixed costs, including the financing
52 See, e.g., Public Interest Organizations
Comments at 35–38 (allowing variable rates will
further discourage wind and solar QF
development); Allco Comments at 9–11 (without
the ability to obtain a fixed long-term forecasted
rate, QF solar energy development will not exist).
53 See NOPR, 168 FERC ¶ 61,184 at P 66.
PO 00000
Frm 00009
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
54645
costs of facilities (i.e., debt repayment
and a return on the equity invested in
the facility).54 Consequently, a fixed
capacity rate in a QF contract based on
a purchasing electric utility’s capacity
rates should typically be sufficient to
recover the QF’s financing costs and
should therefore continue to facilitate
QF financing. We recognize that a QF’s
financing costs may be different from
the purchasing electric utility’s avoided
costs and, therefore, the full avoided
cost rate that the QF receives may not
support the financing of a QF. But this
is a consequence of how Congress
structured PURPA, which sets rates
based on the avoided costs of the
purchasing utility rather than on the
actual costs the QF incurs producing the
power being sold.55
38. Another important aspect of the
variable energy rate/fixed capacity rate
construct is that this is the standard rate
structure used throughout the electric
industry for power sales agreements that
include the sale of capacity.56 That
states will be allowed to require QF
contracts to be structured similarly to
the contract structure used in the rest of
the electric industry has important
implications. In particular, this provides
flexibility to states to ensure that the
avoided cost rate will be closer to the
actual rate the purchasing electric utility
and its customers would have paid if
the purchasing electric utility had
generated this electric energy itself or
purchased such electric energy from
another source. Furthermore, the record
evidence demonstrating significant
amounts of non-QF generation facilities
in operation today shows that the
owners of such facilities are able to
obtain financing based on this same
variable energy rate/fixed capacity rate
54 See Order No. 69, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 30,128
at 30,865.
55 See API, 461 U.S. at 414, 415 (stating that
‘‘Congress did not intend to impose traditional
ratemaking concepts on sales by qualifying facilities
to utilities’’ and that QFs ‘‘would retain an
incentive to produce energy under the full-avoidedcost rule so long as their marginal costs did not
exceed the full avoided cost of the purchasing
utility’’).
56 Cf. Town of Norwood v. FERC, 962 F.2d 20, 21,
24 (D.C. Cir. 1992) (‘‘The rate design before us, like
most wholesale electric rates, consists of separate
monthly demand and energy charges. The demand
component is calculated to recover NEPCO’s fixed
(or capacity-related) costs, such as construction and
debt service, which it incurs regardless of how
much electricity it produces. The energy charge is
designed to recover the company’s variable costs,
which it incurs only in the course of actually
producing electricity; fuel is a prime example. . . .
With the cost outlook constantly in flux due to
changing economic conditions, some degree of
volatility is necessary if prices are to signal the
market accurately—as accurately, that is, as current
prices can anticipate future costs. Price volatility
alone, therefore, cannot provide a ground for
overturning a marginal cost rate structure.’’).
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
54646
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
construct.57 This represents important
evidence that QFs likewise should be
able to obtain financing under the same
rate construct, especially considering
that QFs benefit from the statutory right
to sell pursuant to a mandatory
purchase obligation while non-QFs do
not have that right.58
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
D. The Rate Changes Implemented by
This Final Rule Put QF Rates on the
Same Footing as Electric Utility Rates
and Are Not Discriminatory
39. The fact that variable energy rate/
fixed capacity rate contracts are
standard in the electric industry also
explains why, contrary to assertions
made by a number of commenters,
allowing states to require such contracts
for QFs is not discriminatory.59 QFs
selling at wholesale pursuant to such
contracts will be selling under the same
rate structure employed in the power
sales contracts typically used elsewhere
in the electric industry, including by
public utilities when they make sales at
wholesale to each other, and QFs will be
doing so at full avoided cost rates—the
highest rates permitted under PURPA.
40. It is true that electric utilities with
franchised service territories that make
sales at retail are often effectively
guaranteed the recovery of their energy
costs in their retail rates by their state
regulatory authorities—provided that
such costs are prudently incurred. But
the electric utilities’ retail rates are costbased, such that their rates are set based
on costs they actually incur to produce
electricity for their customers.
Importantly, moreover, the incremental
57 EIA, Form EIA–860 detailed data with previous
form data Early Release (EIA–860A/860B) (June 2,
2020), https://www.eia.gov/electricity/data/eia860/
shows 77.6 GW of operational QF nameplate
capacity and 450.453.5 GW of operational non-QF
independent power producer nameplate capacity as
of end 2019.
58 Some commenters raise concerns with the
Commission’s reliance on the financing of non-QF
generation facilities to support the conclusion that
QFs could obtain financing with variable energy
rate contracts, pointing out that the Commission has
not identified any QFs that have obtained financing
under this structure. The reason for this, however,
is that QFs typically do not employ this structure
because currently they are entitled to a fixed energy
rate/fixed capacity rate construct. Accordingly,
evidence regarding the financing of similar types of
independently owned generation projects by nonQFs using such a construct constitutes the best and
most relevant evidence of how it would affect QF
financing.
59 See, e.g., EPSA Comments at 9 (‘‘The NOPR
avoided rate proposal must therefore be rejected
because it puts QFs at a disadvantage to utilityowned generation, in violation of the nondiscrimination mandate under PURPA.’’); Public
Interest Organizations Comments at 51 (‘‘[L]imiting
QFs to contracts providing no price certainty for
energy values, while non-QF generation regularly
obtains fixed price contracts and utility-owned
generation receives guaranteed cost recovery from
captive ratepayers, constitutes discrimination.’’).
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
energy costs that an electric utility will
recover from its retail customers at an
incremental level would be the same
energy costs that are used in
determining the electric utilities’
avoided costs that will, in turn, set the
as-available avoided cost rates to be
charged by QFs.
41. Thus, QF variable energy rate/
fixed capacity rate contracts not only
would be structured similarly to the
standard wholesale power sales
agreements used in the electric industry,
but application of traditional cost-based
ratemaking principles to sales by QFs is
exactly what would be required in order
to provide QFs with the same
guaranteed cost recovery that applies to
electric utilities. Guaranteeing QFs cost
recovery is fundamentally inconsistent
with PURPA, which sets the rate the QF
is paid at the purchasing electric
utility’s avoided cost, not at the QF’s
cost. Such a rate structure is not
discriminatory.
E. The PURPA Compliance Issues
Raised by Some Commenters Are
Outside the Scope of This Rulemaking
Proceeding
42. Finally, several commenters assert
that certain states located outside of
RTO/ISO markets are dominated by
large integrated public utilities whose
state commissions do not implement
PURPA correctly.60 They argue that, as
a consequence, there is little
development of independent
generation—QFs or otherwise—in those
states. They assert that the proposals in
the NOPR might be appropriate in states
with RTO/ISO markets that are subject
to significant competition, but would
only make matters worse outside of the
RTO/ISO markets.
43. As explained above, several
changes implemented by this final rule
ensure that the PURPA Regulations will
continue to encourage QF development.
Other changes, such as allowing
variable energy rates in QF contracts,
not only ensure the PURPA Regulations
are consistent with PURPA but also
address some states’ primary concern
with the current PURPA Regulations,
i.e., the Commission’s now allowing
states the flexibility to set variable
energy rates could mitigate the states’
reluctance to implement PURPA in a
way that better encourages development
60 American Dams Comments at 5–6; Biological
Diversity Comments at 13; CA Cogeneration
Comments at 6–7; Con Edison Comments at 2;
ELCON Comments at 7–8; EPSA Comments at 1–
2; IdaHydro Comments at 5; NIPPC, CREA, REC,
and OSEIA Comments at 14–15; Solar Energy
Industries Comments at 15–20, 24; SC Solar
Alliance Comments at 3–4; Two Dot Wind
Comments at 14–19.
PO 00000
Frm 00010
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
of QFs. For example, the Idaho
Commission has indicated that its
current policy of limiting QF contracts
to two years is based on its concern
about fixed QF rates, and that the ability
to require variable energy rates could
lead to longer contract terms.61 We
expect that these changes could
facilitate QF development in states
where little QF capacity has been added
to date.
44. Further, commenters’ claims about
lack of QF development outside of the
RTO/ISO markets appear to be
overstated. For example, the most recent
data from the U.S. Energy Information
Administration (EIA) on the total
amount of wind and solar QF capacity
in each state shows that 9 of the 20
states with the greatest combined wind
and solar QF capacity are located
outside of the RTO/ISO markets.62 Of
these 9 states, three are located in the
Southeast—the region asserted by
commenters to be the most hostile to
PURPA—including North Carolina,
which has the highest total amount of
wind and solar QF capacity in the
country.63 Other states in the top 20
include Idaho—with the fourth most
wind and solar QF capacity—and
Oregon,64 two states that have been
criticized as being hostile to PURPA.
EIA data also shows that five of the top
10 states in terms of renewable QF
capacity additions from 2008–17 are
located outside of the RTO/ISO markets,
including North Carolina (with the most
renewable QF capacity additions),
Idaho, Georgia, and Oregon,65 each of
61 See Idaho Commission Comments at 4 (stating
that an energy rate established at the time of
contract formation that provides for ‘‘revisions to
the energy rate at regular intervals, consistent with,
for example, a purchasing electric utility’s
[integrated resource plan] to reflect updated
avoided cost calculations’’ would allow states to
consider longer term contracts without putting
ratepayers at risk).
62 EIA, Form EIA–860 detailed data with previous
form data (EIA–860A/860B) Release date (June 2,
2020), https://www.eia.gov/electricity/data/eia860/.
The top 20 states with combined QF solar and wind
nameplate capacity in 2018 were: (1) California,
Texas, Minnesota, Oklahoma, Massachusetts, New
Mexico, Nebraska, New Jersey, Michigan, New
York, Illinois (all fully or partially inside RTOs/
ISOs); and (2) North Carolina, Idaho, Utah, South
Carolina, Georgia, Oregon, Colorado, Arizona,
Wyoming(outside of RTOs/ISOs). We note that
some of these states are located in both RTO/ISO
and non-RTO/ISO regions.
63 Id. We note that five of the 20 states with the
most solar capacity—perhaps a better measure of
the Southeast Region’s PURPA compliance given
the lack of wind resources in this region—are
located in the Southeast.
64 Id.
65 See EIA, PURPA-qualifying capacity increases,
but it’s still a small portion of added renewables
(Aug. 16, 2018), https://www.eia.gov/
todayinenergy/detail.php?id=36912.
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
which commenters have identified as
being hostile to PURPA.
45. But whether any individual state
has or has not failed to implement the
PURPA Regulations properly is not an
issue for this final rule, which
implements changes to the PURPA
Regulations but does not modify
Commission’s rules for addressing
claims that states are not complying
with the Commission’s existing PURPA
Regulations. We promulgate this final
rule based on the expectation that the
states will fulfill their legal obligation to
implement the Commission’s PURPA
Regulations as revised.66
46. Further, although Congress
required the Commission to establish
the general parameters for establishing
QF rates, Congress delegated to the
states—not the Commission—the role to
set QF rates.67 To the extent that any
entity believes a state is failing to
implement the Commission’s PURPA
Regulations, PURPA section 210(h)
provides that entity an avenue to seek
relief.68
III. Background
A. Passage of PURPA in 1978 and the
Commission’s Promulgation of Its
PURPA Regulations in 1980
47. PURPA was enacted in 1978 as
part of a package of legislative proposals
intended to reduce the country’s
dependence on oil and natural gas,
which at the time were in short supply
and subject to dramatic price increases.
PURPA sets forth a framework to
encourage the development of
alternative generation resources that do
not rely on traditional fossil fuels (i.e.,
oil, natural gas and coal) and
cogeneration facilities that make more
efficient use of the heat produced from
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
66 16
U.S.C. 824a–3(f)(1). The same obligation to
implement the Commission’s PURPA Regulations
as revised, we note, is imposed on nonregulated
electric utilities. 16 U.S.C. 824–3(f)(2).
67 See 16 U.S.C. 824a–3(f)(1) (‘‘[E]ach State
regulatory authority shall, after notice and
opportunity for public hearing, implement such
rule (or revised rule) for each electric utility for
which it has ratemaking authority.’’).
68 If the Commission, in response to a petition for
enforcement under PURPA section 210(h) against a
state regulatory authority, chooses not to initiate an
enforcement action within 60 days of the filing of
the petition, the statute authorizes the petitioning
electric utility or QF to itself initiate a suit directly
against the state in U.S. District Court. 16 U.S.C.
824a–3(h)(2)(B). The same statutory provision
similarly governs petitions for enforcement against
nonregulated electric utilities. Id. PURPA section
210(g) also provides for review of state regulatory
authorities and nonregulated electric utilities in
state fora. 16 U.S.C. 824a–3(g). The Commission’s
policies with respect to PURPA enforcement are
more fully set out in its Policy Statement Regarding
the Commission’s Enforcement Role Under Section
210 of the Public Utility Regulatory Policies Act of
1978, 23 FERC ¶ 61,304 (1983).
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
the fossil fuels that were then
commonly used in the production of
electricity.
48. To accomplish this goal, PURPA
section 210(a) directs that the
Commission ‘‘prescribe, and from time
to time thereafter revise, such rules as
[the Commission] determines necessary
to encourage cogeneration and small
power production,’’ 69 including rules
requiring electric utilities to offer to sell
electricity to, and purchase electricity
from, QFs. PURPA section 210(f)
required each state regulatory authority
and nonregulated electric utility
(together, states) to implement the
Commission’s rules.
49. In 1980, the Commission issued
Order Nos. 69 and 70, which
promulgated the required rules that,
with limited exceptions, remain in
effect today.70 The Commission
explained that, at the time of the
passage of PURPA, cogenerators and
small power producers faced three
major obstacles: (1) Electric utilities
were not required to purchase these
generators’ electric output or to make
purchases at an appropriate rate; (2)
electric utilities sometimes charged
discriminatorily high rates for backup
services; and (3) cogenerators and small
power producers ran the risk of being
considered public utilities themselves
and thus being subject to state and
federal regulation as utilities.71 Further,
at that time, there was no open access
transmission and little competition in
electric wholesale markets. Electric
utilities were vertically-integrated and
held dominant market positions. As a
result of their control over transmission
access, it was virtually impossible for
third parties—whether independent
power producers or other electric
utilities—to compete with them to make
sales of electricity.
50. Given the Congressional mandate
described above, the Commission
determined in Order No. 69 to set rates
69 16
U.S.C. 824a–3(a).
No. 69, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 30,128;
Small Power Production and Cogeneration
Facilities—Qualifying Status, Order No. 70, FERC
Stats. & Regs. ¶ 30,134 (cross-referenced at 10 FERC
¶ 61,230), orders on reh’g, Order No. 70–A, FERC
Stats. & Regs. ¶ 30,159 (cross-referenced at 11 FERC
¶ 61,119) and FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 30,160 (crossreferenced at 11 FERC ¶ 61,166), order on reh’g,
Order No. 70–B, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 30,176
(cross-referenced at 12 FERC ¶ 61,128), order on
reh’g, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 30,192 (1980) (crossreferenced at 12 FERC ¶ 61,306), amending
regulations, Order No. 70–D, FERC Stats. & Regs.
¶ 30,234 (cross-referenced at 14 FERC ¶ 61,076),
amending regulations, Order No. 70–E, FERC Stats.
& Regs. ¶ 30,274 (1981) (cross-referenced at 15
FERC ¶ 61,281).
71 Order No. 69, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 30,128 at
30,863. See infra P 78 & note 112 (addressing how
the PURPA Regulations as revised continue to
address these obstacles).
70 Order
PO 00000
Frm 00011
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
54647
for sales by QFs equal to the purchasing
electric utilities’ avoided costs.72 The
Commission also directed that electric
utilities provide backup electric energy
to QFs on a non-discriminatory basis
and at just and reasonable rates,73 and
that electric utilities interconnect with
QFs.74 Pursuant to section 210(e) of
PURPA,75 the Commission further
provided exemptions from many
provisions of the FPA and state laws
governing utility rates and financial
organization.76
B. Circumstances Leading to the
Commission’s Re-Evaluation of the
PURPA Regulations and the Issuance of
the NOPR
51. In the NOPR, the Commission
described three important changes in
the circumstances that had originally
prompted Congress to pass PURPA in
1978. First, as the Commission
explained, the United States has seen an
unprecedented change in the dynamics
of the natural gas market and the
relevant supply and demand.77 Led by
advancements in production
technologies, primarily in accessing
shale reserves, natural gas supplies
increased dramatically.78 Further, the
EIA forecasted continued supply growth
over the next 25 years.79 In short, as the
Commission found in issuing the NOPR,
there no longer are shortages of natural
gas supply.
52. Second, the Commission found
that, since 1978, the outlook for the
development of alternatives to natural
gas and oil-fired generation resources,
such as renewable resources, has
changed equally dramatically.80 The
once-nascent renewables industry has
grown and matured over the past 40
72 18
CFR 292.304(a)(2); see API, 461 U.S. at 412–
18.
73 Order No. 69, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 30,128 at
30,887–90; see also 18 CFR 292.305.
74 Order No. 69, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 30,128 at
30,874; see also 18 CFR 292.303(c).
75 16 U.S.C. 824a–3(e).
76 Order No. 69, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 30,128 at
30,864; accord id. at 30,863, 30,894–96; see also 18
CFR 292.601–.602.
77 NOPR, 168 FERC ¶ 61,184 at P 19.
78 Domestic natural gas production, which
appeared to peak in the early 1970s at 21.7 Tcf per
year, increased from 18.1 Tcf in 2005 to 30.4 Tcf
in 2018. EIA, Monthly Energy Review (Aug. 27,
2019) (in table 4.1 see column labeled ‘‘Natural Gas
Production (Dry)’’ on the Annual tab of the xls
version), https://www.eia.gov/totalenergy/data/
monthly/.
79 EIA’s forecast showed supplies increasing to
nearly 40 Tcf by 2035 and 43 Tcf by 2050. EIA,
Annual Energy Outlook 2018, at tbl.13 (Jan. 24,
2019) (in table see row labeled ‘‘Dry Gas
Production’’ under the reference case) (Annual
Energy Outlook 2019), https://www.eia.gov/
outlooks/aeo/data/browser/#/?id=13AEO2019&cases=ref2018&sourcekey=0.
80 NOPR, 168 FERC ¶ 61,184 at P 20.
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
54648
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
years and has only accelerated
subsequent to the Energy Policy Act of
2005’s amendment of PURPA. The
Commission noted that the cost of
building renewable facilities has
decreased substantially to the point that
the cost of renewable resources is now
or is shortly expected to approach the
cost of traditional electric generation.81
The Commission also recognized that
renewable resources (including hydro)
provide a significant share of the
electricity currently generated in the
United States,82 that most renewable
resources today are not QFs,83 and that
65 percent of capacity additions in 2019
were expected to come from renewable
resources.84
53. Third, the introduction of QFs as
competing sources of electricity to the
incumbent electric utilities has led to
the development of significant non-QF
independent power production.85 In
81 Id. (citing EIA, Updated Capital Cost Estimates
for Utility Scale Electricity Generating Plants,
https://www.eia.gov/analysis/studies/powerplants/
capitalcost/; EIA, Levelized Cost and Levelized
Avoided Cost of New Generation Resources in the
Annual Energy Outlook 2019 (Feb. 2019), https://
www.eia.gov/outlooks/aeo/pdf/electricity_
generation.pdf; Lawrence Berkeley National Lab,
Wind Technologies Market Report, https://
emp.lbl.gov/wind-technologies-market-report/).
However, EIA has cautioned against directly
comparing the costs of dispatchable and
nondispatchable generation:
Because load must be continuously balanced,
generating units with the capability to vary output
to follow demand (dispatchable technologies)
generally have more value to a system than less
flexible units (nondispatchable technologies) such
as those using intermittent resources to operate. The
LCOE values for dispatchable and non-dispatchable
technologies are listed separately in the tables
because comparing them must be done carefully.
EIA, Levelized Cost and Levelized Avoided Cost
of New Generation Resources in the Annual Energy
Outlook 2019, at 2 (Feb. 2019), https://www.eia.gov/
outlooks/archive/aeo19/pdf/electricity_
generation.pdf.
82 NOPR, 168 FERC ¶ 61,184 at P 21 (citing EIA,
August 2019 Monthly Energy Review at Figure 7.2a,
https://www.eia.gov/totalenergy/data/monthly;
Office of Energy Projects, Energy Infrastructure
Update For July 2019 at 4 (July 2019), https://
www.ferc.gov/legal/staff-reports/2019/july-energyinfrastructure.pdf).
83 NOPR, 168 FERC ¶ 61,184 at P 22.
84 Id. (citing EIA, Today in Energy, New electric
generating capacity in 2019 will come from
renewables and natural gas (Jan. 10, 2019), https://
www.eia.gov/todayinenergy/detail.php?id=37952
(Form EIA–860M, Preliminary Monthly Electric
Generator Inventory).
85 NOPR, 168 FERC ¶ 61,184 at P 25. The
Commission cited to data showing that that net
generation of energy by non-utility owned
renewable resources in the United States escalated
from 51.7 TWh in 2005 when EPAct 2005 was
passed, to 340 TWh in 2018. This also included
significant growth in non-utility renewable
resources in states outside of RTOs. For example,
net generation by non-utility renewable resources in
the region defined by EIA as the Mountain State
region increased from 3.6 TWh in 2005 to 19.5 TWh
in 2012, and to 42.5 TWh in 2018. Pacific
Northwest (Oregon and Washington) net non-utility
generation from renewable resources increased from
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
addition, RTOs and ISOs have
developed competitive wholesale
electric markets that serve roughly twothirds of electricity consumers in the
United States.86
54. In PURPA section 210(a), Congress
directed not only that the Commission
prescribe regulations, but that the
Commission revise those regulations
‘‘from time to time thereafter.’’ 87 The
Commission determined in the NOPR
that, in light of these dramatic changes
in circumstances since the passage of
PURPA, it was appropriate to review the
PURPA Regulations to determine
whether changes to those regulations
were warranted consistent with our
statutory mandate.88
55. After identifying these three
important changes in the industry that
have taken place since 1980, we further
identified evidence demonstrating that
overestimations of avoided cost have
not been balanced by underestimations,
and that this trend may persist with the
general decline in the cost of
electricity.89
C. Summary of Changes to the PURPA
Regulations Implemented by This Final
Rule
56. We now are revising our PURPA
Regulations based on the record of this
proceeding, including comments
submitted in the technical conference in
Docket No. AD16–16–000 (Technical
Conference),90 the record evidence cited
1.5 TWh in 2005, to 8.7 TWh in 2012, and to 10.6
TWh in 2018. In the Southeast region of the
country, non-utility renewable resources saw a
lesser increase from 2.6 TWh in 2005 to 2.7 TWh
in 2012, but expanded to 6.5 TWh in 2018. NOPR,
168 FERC ¶ 61,184 at P 27 (citing data taken from
EIA’s Electricity Data Browser, www.eia.gov/
electricity/data/browser (select net generation, other
renewables, independent power producers)).
86 ISO/RTO Council, The Role of ISOs and RTOs,
https://isorto.org.
87 16 U.S.C. 824a–3(a).
88 16 U.S.C. 824a–3(b).
89 See NOPR, 168 FERC ¶ 61,184 at P 30.
Evidence submitted in response to the NOPR shows
that, as a result, customers may be paying more
than avoided costs. See infra PP 265 (‘‘Duke Energy
claims that, among the factors contributing to this
overpayment of $2.26 billion for the remainder of
these QF contracts, the primary factor has been the
requirement to offer fixed avoided cost energy rates
during a period of rapidly declining energy
prices’’), 268 (‘‘Massachusetts DPU argues that a 10year, fixed energy rate based on current New
England wholesale energy market prices is highly
likely to diverge from actual energy market prices
over the ten-year contract term and could
significantly harm ratepayers’’).
90 Supplemental Notice of Technical Conference,
Implementation Issues Under the Public Utility
Regulatory Policies Act of 1978, Docket No. AD16–
16–000 (May 9, 2016). The Technical Conference
covered such issues as: (1) Various methods for
calculating avoided cost; (2) the obligation to
purchase pursuant to a LEO; (3) application of the
one-mile rule; and (4) the rebuttable presumption
the Commission has adopted under PURPA section
210(m) that QFs 20 MW and below do not have
PO 00000
Frm 00012
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
in the NOPR, and the comments
submitted in response to the NOPR.
These changes, including modifications
to the proposals made in the NOPR, are
summarized below.91
57. First, we grant states the flexibility
to require that energy rates (but not
capacity rates) in QF power sales
contracts and other LEOs 92 vary in
accordance with changes in the
purchasing electric utility’s as-available
avoided costs at the time the energy is
delivered. Under this change, if a state
exercises this flexibility, a QF no longer
would have the ability to elect to have
its energy rate be fixed, but would
continue to be entitled to a fixed
capacity rate for the term of the contract
or LEO.93
58. Second, we grant states additional
flexibility to allow QFs to have a fixed
energy rate, but to provide that such
state-authorized fixed energy rate can be
based on projected energy prices during
the term of a QF’s contract based on the
anticipated dates of delivery.
59. Third, we grant states flexibility to
set ‘‘as-available’’ QF energy rates as
follows: We are establishing a rebuttal
presumption, rather than a per se rule
as proposed in the NOPR, that the LMP
established in the organized electric
markets defined in 18 CFR 292.309(e),
(f), or (g) represents the as-available
avoided costs of electric utilities located
in these markets.94 So long as this
nondiscriminatory access to competitive organized
wholesale markets.
91 In its post-NOPR comments, Bloom Energy
requested that the Commission ‘‘[u]pdate the
definition of ‘useful thermal energy output’ of a
topping-cycle cogeneration facility to reflect the
commercialization of solid oxide fuel cells that
produce heat for the industrial purpose of
producing hydrogen, a fuel that the fuel cells use
to generate electricity.’’ Bloom Energy Comments at
2. We do not take action on this request in this
proceeding because we do not view this proposal
as a logical outgrowth of the NOPR.
92 The Commission has held that a LEO can take
effect before a contract is executed and may not
necessarily be incorporated into a contract. JD Wind
1, LLC, 129 FERC ¶ 61,148, at P 25 (2009), reh’g
denied, 130 FERC ¶ 61,127 (2010) (‘‘[A] QF, by
committing itself to sell to an electric utility, also
commits the electric utility to buy from the QF;
these commitments result either in contracts or in
non-contractual, but binding, legally enforceable
obligations.’’). For ease of reference, however,
references herein to a contract also are intended to
refer to a LEO that is not incorporated into a
contract.
93 Moreover, any state—whether located in
regions where energy prices are competitively based
or whether located in regions where they are not—
would be permitted to require that the fixed energy
rate established at the time of the contract include
provisions, established at the time the contract is
established, providing for revisions to the energy
rate at regular intervals, consistent with, for
example, a purchasing electric utility’s integrated
resource plan, to reflect updated avoided cost
calculations.
94 These are the markets operated by
Midcontinent Independent System Operator, Inc.
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
presumption is not rebutted, a state can
at its option establish as-available
energy avoided cost rates for QFs selling
to such electric utilities at the LMP.
With respect to QFs selling to electric
utilities located outside of the organized
electric markets defined in 18 CFR
292.309(e), (f), or (g), states have the
option to set as-available energy avoided
cost rates at competitive prices from
liquid market hubs or calculated from a
formula based on natural gas price
indices and specified heat rates,
provided that the states first determine
that such prices represent the
purchasing electric utilities’ avoided
costs. The states would have the
flexibility to choose to adopt one or
more of these options or to continue
setting QF rates under the standards
long established in the PURPA
Regulations.
60. Fourth, states would have the
flexibility to set energy and capacity
rates pursuant to a competitive
solicitation process conducted pursuant
to transparent and non-discriminatory
procedures consistent with the
Commission’s Allegheny standard,
described in this final rule.
61. Fifth, we do not adopt the
proposed rule permitting states with
retail competition to allow relief from
the purchase obligation. We instead
clarify in this final rule that the
Commission’s existing PURPA
Regulations already require that states,
to the extent practicable, must account
for reduced loads in setting QF capacity
rates.
62. Sixth, we modify the
Commission’s ‘‘one-mile rule’’ for
determining whether generation
facilities are considered to be at the
same site for purposes of determining
qualification as a qualifying small
power production facility. Specifically,
we allow electric utilities, state
regulatory authorities, and other
interested parties to show that affiliated
small power production facilities that
use the same energy resource and are
more than one mile apart and less than
10 miles apart actually are at the same
site (with distances one mile or less
apart still irrebuttably at the same site,
and distances 10 miles or more apart
irrebuttably at separate sites). We also
allow a small power production facility
seeking QF status to provide further
information in its certification (whether
a self-certification or an application for
Commission certification) or
(MISO); PJM Interconnection, L.L.C. (PJM); ISO
New England Inc. (ISO–NE); New York
Independent System Operator, Inc. (NYISO);
Electric Reliability Council of Texas (ERCOT);
California Independent System Operator, Inc.
(CAISO); and Southwest Power Pool, Inc. (SPP).
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
recertification (whether a selfrecertification or an application for
Commission recertification) to defend
preemptively against subsequent
challenges, by identifying factors
affirmatively demonstrating that its
facility is indeed at a separate site from
other affiliated small power production
qualifying facilities. We further add a
definition of the term ‘‘electrical
generating equipment’’ to the PURPA
Regulations to clarify how the distance
between facilities is to be calculated.
63. Seventh, we allow an entity to
challenge an initial self-certification or
self-recertification without being
required to file a separate petition for
declaratory order and to pay the
associated filing fee. However, we
clarify in this final rule that such
protests may be made to new
certifications (both self-certifications
and applications for Commission
certification) but to only selfrecertifications and applications for
Commission recertifications making
substantive changes to the existing
certification.
64. Eighth, we revise the
Commission’s regulations implementing
PURPA section 210(m), which provide
for the termination of an electric
utility’s obligation to purchase from a
QF with nondiscriminatory access to
certain markets. Currently, there is a
rebuttable presumption that QFs with a
net capacity at or below 20 MW do not
have nondiscriminatory access to such
markets. We update the rebuttable
presumption for small power
production facilities (but not
cogeneration facilities) from 20 MW to
5 MW and, in this final rule, revise the
regulations to include examples of
factors, among others, that QFs may
argue show that they lack
nondiscriminatory access to such
markets.
65. Finally, we clarify that a QF must
demonstrate commercial viability and a
financial commitment to construct its
facility pursuant to objective and
reasonable state-determined criteria
before the QF is entitled to a contract or
LEO. States may not impose any
requirements for a LEO other than a
showing of commercial viability and a
financial commitment to construct the
facility. We also clarify in this final rule
that, to the extent that the permitting
factor is relied upon, a QF need only
show that it has applied for all required
permits and paid all applicable fees, and
not that it has obtained such permits.
66. As explained in detail in the
relevant sections below, these changes
will enable the Commission to continue
to fulfill its statutory obligations under
sections 201 and 210 of PURPA. We
PO 00000
Frm 00013
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
54649
emphasize that these changes are
effective prospectively for new contracts
or LEOs and for new facility
certifications and recertifications filed
on or after the effective date of this final
rule; we do not by this final rule permit
disturbance of existing contracts or
LEOs or existing facility certifications.
IV. Discussion
A. General Legal Standards Under
PURPA
67. Several comments were submitted
regarding: (1) The requirement in
PURPA section 210(a) that ‘‘the
Commission shall prescribe, and from
time to time thereafter revise, such rules
as it determines necessary to encourage
cogeneration and small power
production’’; and (2) the requirement in
PURPA section 210(b) that rates paid by
purchasing utilities to QFs ‘‘shall not
discriminate against qualifying
cogenerators or qualifying small power
producers.’’ 95 In addition, a claim was
made that the Commission has
unlawfully delegated its authority to the
states. These comments apply to several
of the revisions implemented by this
final rule and therefore are discussed
prior to the discussion of specific
revisions implemented herein.
1. Encouragement of QFs
a. Comments
68. Commenters make two general
arguments regarding the statutory
requirement that the Commission’s
PURPA Regulations should encourage
QFs. First, they note that the statutory
requirement that the PURPA
Regulations encourage QFs is
mandatory and that the Commission has
no discretion to determine that such
encouragement no longer is necessary.
Harvard Electricity Law states that
‘‘Congress’[s] mandate to encourage QFs
is not contingent on industry conditions
and does not expire.’’ 96 Further, they
assert, ‘‘[t]he Commission may not
overwrite Congress’s instruction to issue
rules that it ‘determines necessary to
encourage cogeneration and small
power production.’ ’’ 97 Public Interest
Organizations similarly object to the
NOPR as violating the encouragement
requirement because, they assert, the
NOPR ‘‘reflect[s] a belief that the current
rules support too much QF development
and a desire to reduce the incentives in
current rules for QF development.’’ 98
NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA assert
that ‘‘[t]he Commission cannot take it
95 16
U.S.C. 824a–3(a), (b).
Electricity Law Comments at 1.
97 Id. at 4 (quoting PURPA section 210(a)).
98 Public Interest Organizations Comments at 10.
96 Harvard
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
54650
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
upon itself to change the underlying
policy directives to encourage QFs.’’ 99
69. Public Interest Organizations
advance a second general argument
based on the encouragement
requirement, arguing that ‘‘[t]o amend
the rules, the Commission must first
determine that the actual changes it
proposes increase development and
utilization of QFs.’’ 100 Similarly, Allco
attacks the NOPR on the grounds that
‘‘the proposed changes do not encourage
QF generation.’’ 101
b. Commission Determination
70. We agree with commenters that
PURPA does not provide discretion to
the Commission to determine whether
QFs should be encouraged. That is a
determination left to Congress, and we
have not premised this final rule on a
belief that QFs should not be
encouraged. However, the requirement
that the Commission promulgate
regulations necessary to encourage QFs
is not unbounded. Instead, as noted
briefly earlier, there are statutory
limitations on the extent that the
PURPA Regulations can encourage QFs.
71. First, PURPA section 210(b) sets
out standards with which the
Commission must comply in setting QF
rates. The last sentence of PURPA
section 210(b) sets out an upper limit on
such rates. ‘‘No such rule prescribed
under subsection (a) shall provide for a
rate which exceeds the incremental cost
to the electric utility of alternative
electric energy.’’ 102
72. If there were any doubt from the
statutory language that incremental
costs (avoided costs) are intended to be
a hard cap on QF rates, such doubt is
dispelled by the Conference Report to
PURPA, which provided: ‘‘This
limitation on the rates which may be
required in purchasing from a
cogenerator or small power producer is
meant to act as an upper limit on the
price at which utilities can be required
under this section to purchase electric
energy.’’ 103 The Conference Report also
99 NIPPC,
CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at
29.
100 Public
Interest Organizations Comments at 11.
Comments at 8.
102 Furthermore, PURPA section 210(b)(1)
requires that QF rates be ‘‘just and reasonable to the
electric consumers of the electric utility and in the
public interest.’’ 16 U.S.C. 824a–3(b)(1). Although
the exact scope of the ‘‘just and reasonable to the
electric consumers’’ criterion has never been
addressed explicitly, the Supreme Court held in API
that the requirement in the PURPA Regulations that
QF rates be set at full avoided costs does not violate
this criterion. API, 461 U.S. at 415–16. This ‘‘just
and reasonable to the electric consumers’’ criterion
likely would be violated if the Commission were to
allow a rate above the purchasing electric utility’s
avoided costs.
103 Conf. Rep. at 98 (emphasis added).
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
101 Allco
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
described the reason for the avoided
cost cap on QF rates. ‘‘The provisions of
this section are not intended to require
the rate payers of a utility to subsidize
cogenerators or small power
produc[er]s.’’ 104
73. Therefore, PURPA section 210(b)
imposes an important limit on the
Commission’s ability to encourage QFs
by imposing an upper boundary on the
rates at which QFs may require electric
utilities to purchase their electric
energy. The Commission cannot require
QF rates that exceed the avoided costs
of the purchasing electric utility.105
74. Second, another way in which
Congress limited the Commission’s
ability to encourage QFs was to define
small power production facilities, the
PURPA category applicable to almost all
renewable resources that wish to be
QFs, as having ‘‘a power production
capacity which, together with any other
facilities located at the same site (as
determined by the Commission), is not
greater than 80 megawatts.’’ 106 The
statutory 80 MW limitation, as well as
any definition of ‘‘the same site’’ that
may be established by the Commission,
will of necessity have an effect on the
encouragement of QFs, because it will
limit the capacity of QFs both ab initio
and also for those located at the same
site to 80 MW.
75. Third, Congress amended PURPA
section 210 to add section 210(m),
which provides for termination of the
requirement that an electric utility enter
into a new obligation or contract to
purchase from a QF if the QF has
nondiscriminatory access to certain
defined types of markets.107 We
interpret this amendment as reflecting
Congress’s judgment that these markets
provide adequate encouragement for
those QFs having nondiscriminatory
access to such markets. To the extent
that a party asserts that the termination
of the purchase obligation for QFs with
nondiscriminatory access to these
markets discourages QFs, that party’s
argument is not with the Commission,
but rather with Congress. PURPA
section 210(m) obligates the
Commission to grant any request to
terminate a utility’s obligation to
purchase from a QF with
nondiscriminatory access to the
specified markets.108
104 Id.
(emphasis added).
U.S.C. 824a–3(b)(1).
106 16 U.S.C. 796(17)(A)(ii).
107 See 16 U.S.C. 824a–3(m).
108 Id. (‘‘[N]o electric utility shall be required to
enter into a new contract or obligation to purchase
electric energy from a [QF] if the Commission finds
that the [QF] has nondiscriminatory access to
[specified markets].’’).
105 16
PO 00000
Frm 00014
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
76. Finally, we disagree with any
suggestion that a rule originally adopted
in 1980 cannot be changed once
adopted, or that our revised regulations
cannot be different in how they
encourage QFs than the regulations the
Commission issued in 1980.109 For one
thing, as explained above, PURPA itself
includes certain limitations on the
Commission’s ability to encourage QFs,
and a provision in the final rule
intended to comply with these statutory
limitations cannot be found to violate
PURPA even if such a provision
individually does not affirmatively
encourage QFs to the same degree now
as in 1980. As explained herein, we do
not seek, through this final rule, to cease
encouraging the development of QFs.
Instead, this final rule is intended to
ensure that the Commission is
compliant with the statute in how it
does encourage the development of QFs.
In doing so, the Commission may end
up encouraging QF development
differently from the current PURPA
Regulations, but the Commission’s
regulations continue to encourage QF
development, as contemplated by
PURPA.
77. Many of the commenters’
assertions seem to be based on a reading
of the statute that requires that every
individual change made to the PURPA
Regulations in isolation must
individually encourage QFs
notwithstanding the statute’s
provisions. But, as discussed above,
Congress established boundaries in
PURPA that must be considered, such as
the ‘‘cap’’ on incremental costs; just and
reasonable rates for electric customers;
the 80 MW limit; and whether QFs have
nondiscriminatory access to markets.
Furthermore, the statutory requirement
to encourage QF development applies to
the PURPA Regulations—‘‘such rules as
[the Commission] determines
necessary’’—as a whole.110
78. In that regard, we find that the
Commission’s PURPA Regulations as a
whole when modified by this final rule
continue to encourage the development
of QFs, consistent with PURPA. The
PURPA Regulations in particular,
continue to require that QF rates be set
at full avoided costs, a provision the
Supreme Court described as
‘‘provid[ing] the maximum incentive for
the development of cogeneration and
small power production.’’ 111 In
addition, this final rule retains
provisions of the PURPA Regulations
adopted in 1980 that provide
encouragement through other means
109 See
18 U.S.C. 824a–3(a).
16 U.S.C. 824a–3(a) (emphasis added).
111 API, 461 U.S. at 418.
110 See
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
recognized by the Supreme Court in
FERC v. Miss.112 (e.g., certain regulatory
relief,113 interconnection provisions,114
and requirements that utilities sell
power to QFs that will enable QFs to
continue operations).115 Moreover,
several of the changes implemented by
this final rule also provide additional
encouragement for QFs as described in
more detail below.
that certain aspects of the NOPR are
discriminatory, including those
provisions of the NOPR regarding the
use of LMPs and other competitive rates
to set as-available energy rates,120 to
allow for variable energy rates in QF
contracts,121 and to allow avoided costs
to be set through competitive
solicitations (i.e., requests for proposals
(RFPs)).122
2. Discrimination
b. Commission Determination
82. As an initial matter, we agree with
EPSA that the statutory requirement in
PURPA section 210(b)(1) that QF rates
‘‘shall not discriminate against’’ QFs is
more restrictive than the FPA’s
prohibition against ’unduly
discriminatory’ rates.123 However, the
avoided cost cap on QF rates that limits
the Commission’s ability to encourage
QFs, discussed above, also applies to
the Commission’s ability to address
these claims of discrimination under
PURPA. PURPA section 210(b) makes
clear that ‘‘[n]o such rule prescribed
under subsection (a) shall provide for a
rate which exceeds the incremental cost
to the electric utility of alternative
electric energy.’’ 124
83. We are retaining in this final rule
the requirement that QF rates be set at
a purchasing utility’s full avoided costs.
The Supreme Court held in API that
‘‘the full-avoided-cost rule plainly
satisfies the nondiscrimination
requirement.’’ 125 Although the Court
did not provide a detailed explanation
for this holding, the reasoning is
apparent. If the purchasing utility is
paying the same rate to a QF for power
that it otherwise would have paid for
incremental power, by definition such a
rate could not be discriminatory. But
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
a. Comments
79. Commenters opposing the
proposals in the NOPR also cite to the
statutory requirement in PURPA section
210(b)(1) that QF rates ‘‘shall not
discriminate against’’ QFs. EPSA asserts
that ‘‘[n]otably, this standard is more
restrictive than the [FPA’s] prohibition
against ‘unduly discriminatory’
rates.’’ 116 Public Interest Organizations
state that ‘‘[i]n other statutes,
prohibiting price discrimination
without the modifiers ‘unreasonable’ or
‘undue,’ means any difference in price
for the same commodity.’’ 117
80. In discussing the requirement that
QF rates not be discriminatory, some
commenters compare the treatment
afforded to QFs under the NOPR with
the rate treatment applicable to public
utilities. For example, NIPPC, CREA,
REC, and OSEIA point out that
‘‘[u]tilities can rate-base long-term
investments, thereby ensuring that they
can recover their capital investments
plus an authorized return, and then also
recover their actual operating costs
under traditional cost-of-service
ratemaking.’’ 118 By contrast, Harvard
Electricity Law asserts, ‘‘QFs do not
have the same ability that the electric
utilities have to ‘rate base’ their facilities
and, thereby, guarantee capital
recovery.’’ 119
81. Based on this difference between
utilities and QFs, commenters allege
112 456 U.S. 742, 750–51 (1982) (holding that
Congress ‘‘felt that two problems impeded the
development of nontraditional generating facilities:
(1) Traditional electricity utilities were reluctant to
purchase power from, and to sell power to, the
nontraditional facilities, and (2) the regulation of
these alternative energy sources by state and federal
utility authorities imposed financial burdens upon
the nontraditional facilities and thus discouraged
their development’’ (internal citations omitted)).
113 18 CFR 292.601–02.
114 18 CFR 292.303(c).
115 18 CFR 292.305.
116 EPSA Comments at 8.
117 Public Interest Organizations Comments at 47
(citing FTC v. Anheuser-Busch, Inc., 363 U.S. 536,
549 (1960)).
118 NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at
36; see also IdaHydro Comments at 11; Industrial
Energy Consumers Comments at 12–13; SC Solar
Alliance Comments at 5–10; Solar Energy Industries
Comments at 33, 36–38.
119 Harvard Electricity Law Comments at 28.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
120 See, e.g., Public Interest Organizations
Comments at 64 (stating that the use of competitive
prices to set as-available energy avoided cost rates
is discriminatory because non-QF generators are not
limited to competitive prices and utilities can, and
regularly do, pay effective prices for energy that
exceed the price determined by competitive prices).
121 See, e.g., EPSA Comments at 9 (‘‘The NOPR
avoided rate proposal must therefore be rejected
because it puts QFs at a disadvantage to utilityowned generation, in violation of the nondiscrimination mandate under PURPA.’’); Public
Interest Organizations Comments at 51 (‘‘[L]imiting
QFs to contracts providing no price certainty for
energy values, while non-QF generation regularly
obtains fixed price contracts and utility-owned
generation receives guaranteed cost recovery from
captive ratepayers, constitutes discrimination.’’).
122 See, e.g., Allco Comments at 12 (stating that
allowing a state commission to use a competitive
solicitation price is simply giving another tool to a
state commission to kill QF projects).
123 EPSA Comments at 8.
124 Furthermore, as noted above, PURPA section
210(b)(1) requires that QF rates also be ‘‘just and
reasonable to the electric consumers of the electric
utility and in the public interest.’’ See supra note
102.
125 API, 461 U.S. at 413.
PO 00000
Frm 00015
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
54651
even if it were possible to posit a
situation where the payment of a full
avoided cost rate to a QF somehow were
discriminatory, the Commission
nevertheless would be prohibited by
PURPA section 210(b) from requiring a
rate to be paid to the QF that is above
the full avoided costs of the purchasing
electric utility.
84. For the same reasons, Public
Interest Organizations are mistaken
when they assert that, without the
modifiers ‘‘unreasonable’’ or ‘‘undue,’’
any difference in price for the same
commodity violates PURPA.126 So long
as a QF’s rate is set at the purchasing
utility’s full avoided cost, the QF’s rate
should be the same as the rate the
purchasing utility otherwise would be
paying or the cost it would be incurring,
and such a rate would not be
discriminatory. And, in any event, as
noted above, the Commission cannot
require a rate that is any higher.
85. With respect to comparisons
between QFs, with no guarantee of cost
recovery, and electric utilities, which if
they have a franchised service territory
and sell at retail in that territory are
effectively guaranteed the opportunity
to seek to recover prudently-incurred
costs in their retail rates, we observe
that Congress acknowledged this
difference when enacting PURPA. As
emphasized in the PURPA Conference
Report:
The conferees recognize that cogenerators
and small power producers are different from
electric utilities, not being guaranteed a rate
of return on their activities generally or on
the activities vis a vis the sale of power to
the utility and whose risk in proceeding
forward in the cogeneration or small power
production enterprise is not guaranteed to be
recoverable.127
86. In recognizing this difference and
yet not seeking to eliminate it, Congress
also made clear its intent not to treat
QFs like electric utilities in this regard:
It is not the intention of the conferees that
[QFs] become subject . . . to the type of
examination that is traditionally given to
electric utility rate applications to determine
what is the just and reasonable rate that they
should receive for their electric power.128
87. Based on this legislative history,
the Supreme Court concluded in API
that, ‘‘Congress did not intend to impose
traditional ratemaking concepts on sales
by qualifying facilities to utilities.’’ 129
But application of traditional cost-based
ratemaking principles to sales by QFs is
126 Public Interest Organizations Comments at 47
(citing FTC v. Anheuser-Busch, Inc., 363 U.S. at
549).
127 Conf. Rep. at 97–98 (emphasis added).
128 Id. at 97.
129 API, 461 U.S. at 414.
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
54652
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
exactly what would be required in order
to provide QFs with the same
guaranteed cost recovery that applies to
electric utilities. Also, guaranteeing QFs
cost recovery is fundamentally
inconsistent with PURPA, which sets
the rate the QF is paid at the utility’s
avoided cost, not at the QF’s cost.
88. It therefore is clear that Congress
did not intend for the PURPA
nondiscrimination criterion to require
that QF rates be set in a way that
guarantees recovery of a QF’s own costs,
even as Congress recognized that
franchised electric utilities selling at
retail typically do have such guarantees
for their own costs. Congress thus
withheld from the Commission the
authority to provide to QFs the same
opportunity to recover costs at retail
that franchised electric utilities have to
recover their costs at retail; it was done
by Congress intentionally and cannot be
impermissibly discriminatory.130
3. Unlawful Delegation and the Role of
Nonregulated Electric Utilities
a. Comments
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
89. Allco argues that PURPA section
210(f) requires states to ‘‘implement’’
the Commission’s rules, and that those
rules cannot redelegate the
Commission’s authority. Allco claims
that the statutory requirement to
implement the Commission’s rules
cannot simply be a fac
¸ade for delegating
broad authority to states to undercut
PURPA’s directive that QF small power
production must be encouraged. Allco
concludes that Congress intended for
the Commission to adopt actual rules
rather than ‘‘a menu of factors’’ that
essentially leaves states with all the
discretion as to what to implement in
order to encourage QF generation.131
90. Allco also asserts that the NOPR’s
proposed delegation of authority to
nonregulated electric utilities is an
unconstitutional delegation. According
to Allco, such a delegation would mean
that nonregulated electric utilities (some
of which are among the largest utilities
in the United States) were regulating
themselves. Allco argues that a private
entity such as a nonregulated electric
utility cannot constitutionally be
delegated regulatory power.132
91. Nebraska Board states that there is
no state agency in Nebraska that has
ratemaking authority over retail electric
suppliers and that all retail electric
130 See 16 U.S.C. 824a–3(a) (rules Commission is
directed to prescribe ‘‘may not authorize a [QF] to
make any sale for purposes other than resale’’).
131 Allco Comments at 39–40.
132 Id. at 40 (citing Ass’n of Am. R.R. v. DOT, 721
F.3d 666, 677 (D.C. Cir. 2013), vacated on other
grounds, 135 S. Ct. 1225 (2015)).
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
suppliers are consumer-owned.
Nebraska Board states its understanding
that each retail electric supplier in
Nebraska would have jurisdiction to
exercise flexibilities provided to states
in the NOPR.
92. Public Interest Organizations
argue that the Commission failed to
comply with PURPA section 210’s
requirement to consult with federal and
state regulatory agencies with
ratemaking authority.133
b. Commission Determination
93. Allco’s unlawful delegation claims
are misplaced. By enacting PURPA
section 210(f)(1), Congress delegated to
the states the obligation to implement
the Commission’s PURPA rules, and the
Commission is acting consistent with
that delegation. Congress’s delegation to
the states was upheld in FERC v.
Miss.134 and we are ensuring that the
rules we have imposed abide by all the
terms of the statute. Further, the
Commission’s current PURPA
Regulations, promulgated in 1980, set
forth a list of factors that the states are
to consider, ‘‘to the extent practicable,’’
in setting QF rates.135 In so doing, the
Commission emphasized that states
have ‘‘great latitude in determining the
manner of implementation of the
Commission’s rules, provided that the
manner chosen is reasonably designed
to implement the requirements of
Subpart C [which includes the pricing
rules of 18 CFR 292.304].’’ 136 This final
rule adds factors that must be taken into
account to the extent practicable in
setting rates, while retaining the ‘‘great
latitude’’ the states always have had to
implement the PURPA Regulations and
which have been an important feature of
the Commission’s PURPA Regulations
since their inception.
94. With respect to Allco’s claim that
the NOPR proposed an unconstitutional
delegation to nonregulated electric
utilities, we note that PURPA section
210(f)(2) specifically provides that
‘‘each nonregulated electric utility shall,
after notice and opportunity for public
hearing, implement’’ the Commission’s
133 Public Interest Organizations Comments at 19
(citing 16 U.S.C. 824a–3(a)).
134 456 U.S. at 760 (‘‘FERC has declared that state
commissions may implement this by, among other
things, ‘an undertaking to resolve disputes between
qualifying facilities and electric utilities arising
under [PURPA].’ ’’).
135 18 CFR 292.304(e).
136 Order No. 69, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 30,128 at
30,891–92. The Commission explained that ‘‘[s]uch
latitude is necessary in order for implementation to
accommodate local conditions and concerns, so
long as the final plan is consistent with statutory
requirements.’’ Policy Statement Regarding the
Commission’s Enforcement Role Under Section 210
of the Public Utility Regulatory Policies Act of 1978,
23 FERC ¶ 61,304,at 61,646.
PO 00000
Frm 00016
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
rules regarding the rates to be paid to
QFs. Consistent with this statutory
provision, the PURPA Regulations
regarding the setting of QF rates have
applied to nonregulated electric utilities
since those regulations were
promulgated in 1980.137 The final rule
does nothing more than continue to
implement this statutory requirement in
the same way it always has been
implemented. Given PURPA’s unique
statutory scheme involving state
regulatory authorities, nonregulated
electric utilities, QFs, and the
Commission, we therefore reject Allco’s
assertion that the rules proposed in the
NOPR—and adopted in this final rule—
establish an unconstitutional delegation
of authority to a private entity.138 And
it is beyond the Commission’s purview
to consider whether this statutory grant
is constitutional.139 Accordingly, when
we refer to states in this final rule, we
usually are referring to both state
regulatory authorities and nonregulated
electric utilities.
95. Regarding Public Interest
Organizations assertion that the
Commission failed to comply with
PURPA section 210’s requirement to
consult with federal and state regulatory
agencies with ratemaking authority, we
find that the 2016 Technical
Conference’s invitation to the public
(including state regulatory authorities)
to speak, as well as the notice and
comment process on the NOPR itself,
encompasses the required
consultation.140 The notices soliciting
137 See Order No. 69, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 30,128
at 30,864 (‘‘The implementation of these rules is
reserved to the State regulatory authorities and
nonregulated electric utilities.’’).
138 See Allco Comments at 40.
139 Finnerty v. Cowen, 508 F.2d 979, 982 (2d Cir.
1974) (explaining that administrative agencies
‘‘have neither the power nor the competence to pass
on the constitutionality of administrative or
legislative action’’) (quoting Murray v. Vaughn, 300
F. Supp. 688, 695 (D. R.I. 1969)); see also Gibas v.
Saginaw Mining Co., 748 F.2d 1112, 1117 (6th Cir.
1984) (‘‘[A]dministrative bodies like the Board do
not have the authority to adjudicate the validity of
legislation which they are charged with
administering.’’); Spiegel, Inc. v. FTC, 540 F.2d 287,
294 (7th Cir. 1976) (finding that the federal agency
erred by making a constitutional determination);
Downen v. Warner, 481 F.2d 642, 643 (9th Cir.
1973) (‘‘Resolving a claim founded solely upon a
constitutional right is singularly suited to a judicial
forum and clearly inappropriate to an
administrative board.’’); cf. Woodrow v. FERC, 2020
WL 2198050, at *9 (D.D.C. May 6, 2020) (‘‘When
Congress creates an intricate statutory-review
process that incorporates agency consideration and
ultimately an avenue to petition an Article III court,
we assume it wants that scheme to control.’’).
140 See Notice Inviting Post-Technical Conference
Comments, Implementation Issues Under the Public
Utility Regulatory Policies Act of 1978, Docket No.
AD16–16–000 (Sept. 6, 2016); Supplemental Notice
of Technical Conference, Implementation Issues
Under the Public Utility Regulatory Policies Act of
1978, Docket No. AD16–16–000 (Mar. 4, 2016)
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
comments were open to all state
authorities. Indeed, since the
Commission first announced that
technical conference and up to our
receipt of comments on the NOPR,
representatives from several states have
filed comments expressing their views
on how the Commission should
implement PURPA.
B. QF Rates
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
1. Overview
96. PURPA requires that the
Commission promulgate rules, to be
implemented by the states,141 that
‘‘shall insure’’ that the rates electric
utilities pay for purchases of electric
energy from QFs meet the statutory
criteria described above, including that
‘‘[n]o such rule . . . shall provide for a
rate which exceeds’’ the purchasing
utility’s ‘‘incremental cost . . . of
alternative electric energy.’’ 142 Under
PURPA, such rates must: (1) Be just and
reasonable to the electric consumers of
the electric utility and in the public
interest; (2) not discriminate against
qualifying cogenerators or qualifying
small power producers; 143 and, as noted
above, (3) not exceed ‘‘the incremental
cost to the electric utility of alternative
electric energy,’’ 144 which is ‘‘the cost
to the electric utility of the electric
energy which, but for the purchase from
such cogenerator or small power
producer, such utility would generate or
purchase from another source.’’ 145 The
‘‘incremental cost to the electric utility
of alternative electric energy’’ referred to
in prong (3) above, which sets out a
statutory upper bound on a QF rate, has
been consistently referred to by the
Commission and industry by the shorthand phrase ‘‘avoided cost,’’ 146
(announcing preliminary agenda and inviting
interested speakers).
141 Nonregulated electric utilities implement the
requirements of PURPA with respect to themselves.
An electric utility that is ‘‘nonregulated’’ is any
electric utility other than a ‘‘state regulated electric
utility.’’ 16 U.S.C. 2602(9). The term ‘‘state
regulated electric utility,’’ in contrast, means any
electric utility with respect to which a state
regulatory authority has ratemaking authority. 16
U.S.C. 2602(18). The term ‘‘state regulatory
authority,’’ as relevant here, means a state agency
which has ratemaking authority with respect to the
sale of electric energy by an electric utility. 16
U.S.C. 2602(17).
142 16 U.S.C. 824a–3(b).
143 16 U.S.C. 824a–3(b)(1)–(2).
144 16 U.S.C. 824a–3(b).
145 16 U.S.C. 824a–3(d) (emphasis added).
146 See 18 CFR 292.101(b)(6) (defining avoided
costs in relation to the statutory terms); see also
Order No. 69, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 30,128 at 30,865
(‘‘This definition is derived from the concept of ‘the
incremental cost to the electric utility of alternative
electric energy’ set forth in section 210(d) of
PURPA. It includes both the fixed and the running
costs on an electric utility system which can be
avoided by obtaining energy or capacity from
qualifying facilities.’’).
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
although the term ‘‘avoided cost’’ itself
does not appear in PURPA.
97. In addition, the PURPA
Regulations currently provide a QF two
options for how to sell its power to an
electric utility. The QF may choose to
sell as much of its energy as it chooses
when the energy becomes available,
with the rate for the sale calculated at
the time of delivery (frequently referred
to as a so-called ‘‘as-available’’ sale and
rate).147 Alternatively, the QF may
choose to sell pursuant to a legally
enforceable obligation or LEO (such as
a contract) over a specified term.148
98. If the QF chooses to sell under the
second option, the PURPA Regulations
then provide the QF the further option
of receiving, in terms of pricing, either:
(1) The purchasing electric utility’s
avoided cost calculated at the time of
delivery; 149 or (2) the purchasing
electric utility’s avoided cost calculated
and fixed at the time the LEO is
incurred.150
99. In implementing the PURPA
Regulations, the Commission recognized
that a contract with avoided costs
calculated at the time a LEO is incurred
could exceed the electric utility’s
avoided costs at the time of delivery in
the future, thereby seemingly violating
PURPA’s requirement that QFs not be
paid more than an electric utility’s
avoided costs. But the Commission
believed that the fixed avoided cost rate
might also turn out to be lower than the
electric utility’s avoided costs over the
course of the contract and that, ‘‘in the
long run, ’overestimations’ and
‘underestimations’ of avoided costs will
balance out.’’ 151 The Commission’s
justification for allowing QFs to fix their
147 18
CFR 292.304(d)(1).
CFR 292.304(d)(2)(i)–(ii); see also FLS, 157
FERC ¶ 61,211 at P 21 (citing 18 CFR 292.304(d)).
The LEO or contract is frequently referred to as a
long-term transaction, when contrasted with an ‘‘as
available’’ sale and rate.
149 18 CFR 292.304(d)(2)(i).
150 18 CFR 292.304(d)(2)(ii). Rates calculated at
the time of a LEO (for example, a contract) do not
violate the requirement that the rates not exceed
avoided costs if they differ from avoided costs at the
time of delivery. 18 CFR 292.304(b)(5).
151 Order No. 69, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 30,128 at
30,880. See also 18 CFR 292.304(b)(5) (‘‘In the case
in which the rates for purchases are based upon
estimates of avoided costs over the specific term of
the contract or other legally enforceable obligation,
the rates for such purchases do not violate this
subpart if the rates for such purchases differ from
avoided costs at the time of delivery.’’); Entergy
Servs., Inc., 137 FERC ¶ 61,199, at P 56 (2011)
(‘‘Many avoided cost rates are calculated on an
average or composite basis, and already reflect the
variations in the value of the purchase in the lower
overall rate. In such circumstances, the utility is
already compensated, through the lower rate it
generally pays for unscheduled QF energy, for any
periods during which it purchases unscheduled QF
energy even though that energy’s value is lower
than the true avoided cost.’’).
148 18
PO 00000
Frm 00017
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
54653
rate at the time of the LEO for the entire
life of the contract was that fixing the
rate provides ‘‘certainty with regard to
return on investment in new
technologies.’’ 152
100. In the NOPR, the Commission
proposed to revise its PURPA
Regulations to permit states to
incorporate competitive market forces in
setting QF rates. Specifically, the
Commission proposed to revise its
PURPA Regulations with regard to QF
rates to provide states with the
flexibility to:
• Require that ‘‘as-available’’ QF
energy rates paid by electric utilities
located in RTO/ISO markets be based on
the market’s LMP, or similar energy
price derived by the market, in effect at
the time the energy is delivered.
• require that ‘‘as-available’’ QF
energy rates paid by electric utilities
located outside of RTO/ISO markets be
based on competitive prices determined
by: (1) liquid market hub energy prices;
or (2) formula rates based on observed
natural gas prices and a specified heat
rate.
• require that energy rates under QF
contracts and LEOs be based on asavailable energy rates determined at the
time of delivery rather than being fixed
for the term of the contract or LEO.
• implement an alternative approach
of requiring that the fixed energy rate be
calculated based on estimates of the
present value of the stream of revenue
flows of future LMPs or other acceptable
as-available energy rates at the time of
delivery.
• require that energy and/or capacity
rates be determined through a
competitive solicitation process, such as
an RFP, with processes designed to
ensure that the competitive solicitation
is performed in a transparent, nondiscriminatory fashion.153
101. Although the Commission
proposed to modify how the states are
permitted to calculate avoided costs, it
did not propose to terminate the
requirement that the states continue to
calculate, and to set QF rates at, such
avoided costs.
102. We adopt these proposals in this
final rule, with certain modifications.
Each such proposal, and our final
determination, is discussed further
below.
2. Use of Competitive Market Prices To
Set As-Available Avoided Cost Rates
103. In addition to commenting on the
specific methods for determining asavailable avoided cost rates, several
152 Order No. 69, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 30,128 at
30,880.
153 NOPR, 168 FERC ¶ 61,184 at PP 32–33.
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
54654
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
commenters addressed more generally
the Commission’s proposal in the NOPR
that states be given the flexibility to use
competitive market prices to set such
rates. Before discussing the specific
methods proposed in the NOPR, we first
discuss the determination that the use of
competitive market prices, however
determined, can be an appropriate
approach to determining as-available
avoided cost rates.
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
a. NOPR Proposal
104. In the NOPR, the Commission
proposed to give the states the flexibility
to use competitive market prices to set
as-available avoided cost rates. The
Commission stated its belief that
consideration of transparent,
competitive market prices in
appropriate circumstances would help
to identify an electric utility’s avoided
costs in a simpler, more transparent,
and more predictable manner that
would, in conjunction with the
Commission’s other existing and
proposed PURPA Regulations, act to
encourage QFs.154
105. For those utilities located in
RTO/ISO markets, the NOPR identified
LMP as a competitive market price that
states could choose to adopt as
representing an as-available avoided
energy cost. The Commission explained
that LMP could provide an accurate
measure of the varying actual avoided
costs for each receipt point on an
electric utility’s system where the utility
receives power from QFs.155 In addition
to these benefits, the Commission
observed that LMPs, in contrast to the
administrative pricing methodologies
used to set as-available QF rates by
many states, could promote the more
efficient use of the transmission grid,
promote the use of the lowest-cost
generation, and provide for transparent
price signals.156
106. For utilities located outside of
RTO/ISO markets, the NOPR proposed
to allow states to use two other potential
competitively priced measures of a
utility’s as-available avoided cost rates:
(1) Energy rates established at liquid
market hubs; or (2) energy rates
determined pursuant to formulas based
on natural gas price indices and a proxy
heat rate for an efficient natural gas
combined-cycle generating facility. In
each such case, though, the state would
need to find that that price reasonably
P 13.
P 45.
156 Id. P 48 (citing Cal. Indep. Sys. Operator
Corp., 105 FERC ¶ 61,140, at PP 48–50 (2003); Cf.
Price Formation in Energy and Ancillary Servs.
Mkts Operated by Reg’l Transmission Orgs. and
Indep. Sys. Operators, 153 FERC ¶ 61,221, at P 2
(2015)).
represents a competitive market price
that represents the avoided costs of the
purchasing electric utility.157
b. Comments
107. Allco argues that the only reason
for including the use of competitive
market prices to set as-available energy
rates is to create a menu of prices from
which a state regulatory authority or
unregulated electric utility can choose
the lowest price. Allco claims this
proposal would not encourage QF
generation, would be inconsistent with
the rules of economic dispatch, and
would be inconsistent with the language
of PURPA.158 BluEarth makes similar
arguments.159 In contrast, El Paso
Electric argues that state regulatory
authorities should be able to set avoided
cost rates based on the lesser of a market
hub price or a combined cycle price.160
Similarly, the California Commission
argues that utilities located in organized
markets (not just non-organized
markets) should also be expressly
permitted to use any competitive price
(whether derived from a market hub,
competitive solicitation, or a combined
cycle price) to set avoided cost rates.
The California Commission also argues
that states should have the ability to use
competitive prices for not just asavailable energy pricing, but also for
capacity pricing, and proposes minor
modifications to the relevant regulation
text proposed in the NOPR in order to
clarify these points.161
108. The California Commission
argues that the proposed regulations
should be modified to: (1) Define the
newly permissible avoided cost
methodologies within the definitions
section of Part 292; (2) eliminate any
perception that the new methodologies
can only be used to set avoided costs for
as-available energy; (3) allow any
appropriate market-based methodology
to set avoided-cost rates for energy,
capacity or both; and (4) define
‘‘Organized Electric Market.’’ 162 The
California Commission believes that the
new regulations should indicate: (1)
That they do not provide states any
more flexibility than they already have;
(2) that utilities located in organized
markets may use any Market Hub Price,
Competitive Solicitation Price, or
Combined Cycle Price to establish
avoided-cost rates; and (3) that a price
based on LMP or a Competitive Price is
154 Id.
155 Id.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
157 NOPR,
168 FERC ¶ 61,184 at P 51.
Comments at 8.
159 BluEarth Comments at 2.
160 El Paso Electric Comments at 3–4.
161 California Commission Comments at 23–27.
162 Id. at 11–14.
158 Allco
PO 00000
Frm 00018
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
just and reasonable and
nondiscriminatory.163
109. Some commenters object to the
use of competitive markets prices on the
grounds that these competitive prices
represent only short-term, or spot prices
that do not reflect the long-term
marginal costs and other costs avoided
by purchasing utilities.164 Similarly,
some commenters assert that
competitive prices cannot support the
financing of QFs.165
110. Public Interest Organizations
argue that using competitive prices to
set as-available energy avoided cost
rates is discriminatory because non-QF
generators are not limited to competitive
prices and utilities can, and regularly
do, pay effective prices for energy that
exceed the price determined by
competitive prices.166 Several other
commenters express concern about
setting QF prices by referencing shortterm liquid hub prices while allowing
utilities to rate base and recover their
long-term investments.167 Industrial
Energy Consumers argue that, if the
Commission implements the liquid
market hub proposal, there must be
assurances that utilities’ self-builds face
the same market risk exposure as QFs.
For example, they argue, if states expose
QFs to variable rates for their energy
output, utility-owned generation should
also be exposed to variable rates for
their energy output.168
111. Several commenters assert that
QF rates should reflect benefits other
than the avoided cost of energy.169 For
example, Biogas and Biomass Power
state that non-energy benefits, like waste
reduction and economic development
must be incorporated into avoided cost
determinations.170 Biogas and Resources
for the Future state that locational
values should be incorporated into
avoided cost calculations.171 American
Dams states that utilities’ avoided
163 Id.
at 23–25.
Comments at 11; Southeast Public
Interest Organizations Comments at 19; NIPPC,
CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 52, 55 (citing
Exelon Wind I, LLC, 140 FERC ¶ 61,152, at P 52
(2012)); Union of Concerned Scientists Comments
at 6.
165 BluEarth Renewables Comments at 2;
Biological Diversity at 8; Covanta Comments at 9;
Public Interest Organization Comments at 43–44.
166 Public Interest Organizations Comments at 64.
167 IdaHydro Comments at 11; Industrial Energy
Consumers Comments at 12–13.
168 Industrial Energy Consumers Comments at 12–
13.
169 Biogas Comments at 1–2; Biomass Power
Comments at 1; EPSA Comments at 14–16;
Resources for the Future Comments at 4; Xcel
Comments at 3–5.
170 Biogas Comments at 2; Biomass Power
Comments at 1.
171 Biogas Comments at 1; Resources for the
Future Comments at 4.
164 IdaHydro
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
transmission charges should be
included in avoided cost
determinations.172 Xcel states that
hidden integration and utility planning
costs should also be incorporated into
avoided cost calculations.173 American
Dams argues that for high capital
projects like hydro, the Commission
should consider longer-term public
benefits and not just short-term market
pricing.174
112. Solar Energy Industries asserts
that payments based on the LMP should
not relieve the purchasing utility of the
requirement to compensate the QF for
any values in addition to electricity
(e.g., renewable energy credits,
frequency response capabilities, prorated capacity value, etc.).175
113. California Utilities request that
the Commission clarify that states may
but are not required to consider state
policies when establishing avoided
costs.176 Harvard Electricity Law
requests that the Commission clarify its
rule allowing states to set tiered rates.177
c. Commission Determination
114. As an initial matter, we observe
that some of the concerns raised by
commenters about the use of
competitive market prices to set asavailable energy rates for QFs are based
on the incorrect assumption that the
NOPR proposal would permit states to
use competitive market prices to set asavailable energy rates for QFs even
when competitive market prices are
below the purchasing utility’s avoided
costs. In fact, however, the use of
competitive market prices to set QF
rates is explicitly subject to the
requirement that such prices are equal
to the purchasing utility’s avoided
energy costs.178 As the Supreme Court
noted in API, the full avoided cost rate
requirement represents the maximum
rate permitted under PURPA, and
thereby provides important
encouragement to QFs.179 And as the
Supreme Court also noted in the same
decision, ‘‘the full-avoided-cost rule
plainly satisfies the nondiscrimination
requirement.’’ 180 Further, in requiring
full avoided cost rates, ‘‘[t]he
Commission did not ignore the interest
of electric utility consumers ‘in
172 American
Dams Comments at 4.
Comments at 3–5.
174 American Dams Comments at 2.
175 Solar Energy Industry Comments at 27–28.
176 California Utilities Comments at 18–19.
177 Harvard Electricity Law Comments at 32–33.
178 Arguments that the various competitive
market prices identified in this final rule do not
represent avoided energy costs are addressed below
with respect to each such specific market price.
179 API, 461 U.S. at 413.
180 Id.
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
173 Xcel
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
receiving electric energy at equitable
rates.’ ’’ 181
115. For this reason, Allco is incorrect
when it claims that the competitive
price proposal represents a menu of
prices that a state can select to choose
the lowest rate. In the event that more
than one competitive price option
potentially could apply, the state would
be required to select the option that
reasonably reflects the purchasing
utility’s avoided costs, which is what
PURPA requires.182
116. Further, the record supports the
conclusion that the use of transparent,
competitive market prices provides
encouragement to QFs, represents the
avoided cost, and can ensure that the
rate does not exceed the incremental
cost to the purchasing electric utility. In
addition to the testimony to this effect
presented at the technical conference
and cited in the NOPR,183 the
conclusion is further supported by
comments submitted in response to the
NOPR. For example, NIPPC, CREA,
REC, and OSEIA cite to a report by
Fitch, which explains how Fitch
evaluates the financial strength of
renewable energy projects. In this
report, Fitch states that it gives a
‘‘stronger’’ evaluation to projects with
power sales contract prices that are
‘‘indexed using simple, broad-based
publicly available indexation
formulas.’’ 184 In addition, Solar Energy
Industries notes the difficulties QFs face
in expending large sums to develop
their projects ‘‘[f]or states that do not
publish the avoided costs, or for utilities
that treat their avoided cost
181 Id.
at 415 (quoting Conf. Rep. at 97).
a competitive market, the transportation
costs between any such two hubs and a QF would
be such that they would make the QF rate the same,
no matter which hub was selected. See FERC,
Energy Primer, A Handbook of Market Basics, at 64
(June 2020), https://www.ferc.gov/marketassessments/guide/energy-primer-2020.pdf (Energy
Primer) (‘‘If there are no transmission constraints,
or congestion, LMPs will not vary significantly
across the RTO footprint. However, when
transmission congestion occurs, LMPs will vary
across the footprint because operators are not able
to dispatch the least-cost generators across the
entire region and some more expensive generation
must be dispatched to meet demand in the
constrained area.’’).
183 See American Forest & Paper Association
Comments, Docket No. AD16–16–000, at 8 (filed
June 8, 2016) (‘‘To the extent possible, these
determinations [of avoided costs] should not be
made in a ‘black box’, but rather, as part of an open
and transparent method and process.’’); EEI
Comments, Docket No. AD16–16–000, at 3 (filed
June 30, 2016) (‘‘Where transparent competitive
markets with day ahead prices exist, there is no
reason to adhere to second-best avoided cost pricing
mechanisms.’’).
184 NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at
37–38 (citing FitchRatings, Global Infrastructure &
Project Finance, Renewable Energy Project Rating
Criteria, at 3 (Feb. 26, 2019), https://
www.fitchratings.com/site/re/10061770).
182 In
PO 00000
Frm 00019
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
54655
methodologies as confidential trade
secrets.’’185
117. We agree with commenters who
assert that competitive market prices
represent only short-run spot prices that
do not reflect electric utilities’ long-run
costs that QFs can displace. However,
we are authorizing states to use
competitive market prices only to
establish as-available energy rates for
QFs. The comments misunderstand the
fundamental difference between the
value to a purchasing utility of such asavailable energy and the value to a
purchasing utility of capacity.
118. A QF has no obligation under the
as-available avoided cost rate provisions
to deliver any set amount of electric
energy at any point in the future, but
merely is paid for the amount of electric
energy actually delivered. Therefore, the
delivery of as-available energy does not
displace any long-term energy the
purchasing electric utility would
generate itself or purchase from another
source but rather allows the purchasing
utility to reduce the amount of energy
it otherwise would generate itself or
purchase from another entity at the time
the QF delivers the energy. Because the
QF has no obligation to deliver any
energy in the future, the utility is unable
to avoid constructing or contracting for
capacity to meet its future needs as a
consequence of the delivery of energy
by the QF. As-available energy rates
therefore appropriately reflect only the
short-run value of energy delivered at
the particular moment in time when and
if the QF has energy available to be
delivered to the utility.
119. A QF can displace an electric
utility’s own generation or purchases
from alternative sources over the longrun when a QF sells capacity to a utility
in addition to as-available energy. In
contrast to as-available energy, a sale of
capacity would typically compensate
the QF for maintaining the capability to
deliver a set amount of energy in the
future (i.e., capital costs),186 and thus
allows the purchasing utility to avoid
the cost of making alternative
arrangements, either through a selfbuild or an alternative purchase, to
obtain that amount of energy.
Consequently, the price of capacity
purchased from a QF would reflect this
long-run avoided cost. And this final
rule does not alter a purchasing utility’s
185 Solar
Energy Industries Comments at 41.
Order No. 69, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 30,128
at 30,885 (‘‘Energy costs are the variable costs
associated with the production of electric energy
(kilowatt-hours). They represent the cost of fuel,
and some operating and maintenance expenses.
Capacity costs are the costs associated with
providing the capability to deliver energy; they
consist primarily of the capital costs of facilities.’’).
186 See
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
54656
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
existing obligation to pay QFs for any
avoided capacity benefit that allows the
utility to avoid acquiring capacity.187
120. For these reasons, we decline to
grant the California Commission’s
request to allow using competitive
prices for not just as-available energy
pricing, but also for capacity pricing.188
We also reject the California
Commission’s request to permit all
electric utilities, both those located in
organized markets and those located in
non-organized market areas, to use any
competitive price (whether a Market
Hub Price or Combined Cycle Price, or
alternatively a Competitive Solicitation
Price) to set avoided cost rates. The
Market Hub Price and Combined Cycle
Price, as well as the Competitive
Solicitation Price are options that
should generally reflect a purchasing
electric utility’s avoided as-available
energy costs in non-RTO/ISO areas,
while the LMP should generally reflect
a purchasing electric utility’s avoided
as-available energy costs in RTO/ISO
market areas.
121. With respect to the
discrimination claims, our decision to
give states the flexibility to use
competitive prices is driven by the fact
that the competitive market price
represents the purchasing utility’s
avoided costs. And, as explained in
Section IV.A.2 above, a rate set at full
avoided costs by definition cannot be
discriminatory and, in any event, the
Commission is without authority under
PURPA section 210(b) to require a rate
above avoided costs.
122. Further, Industrial Energy
Consumers are incorrect when they
suggest that public utility energy rates
do not vary with costs in the same way
that the competitive market prices
potentially applicable to QFs under the
final rule vary. To the contrary, the
Commission and most states provide for
fuel adjustment clauses applicable to
rates, which allow utility rates to adjust
automatically with changes in utility
fuel and purchased power costs.189 And
187 See Order No. 69, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 30,128
at 30,881–86 (describing how states must calculate
avoided capacity costs).
188 See infra sections IV.B.3–5. We note that states
may use competitive solicitations to set both energy
and capacity avoided cost rates. See infra section
IV.B.8.
189 See 18 CFR 35.14 (Fuel Cost and Purchased
Economic Power Adjustment Clauses); ELCON,
Fuel Adjustment Clauses & Other Cost Trackers,
https://elcon.org/fuel-adjustment-clauses-costtrackers (‘‘Fuel adjustment clauses are in effect in
almost all states.’’); NARUC, Staff Subcommittee on
Accounting and Finance, Fuel and Purchased
Power Survey Results (Sept. 23, 2015), https://
pubs.naruc.org/pub/4AA28D50-2354-D714-5149B773EFC3EFEF (stating that only one state surveyed
said that it did not employ a fuel adjustment
clause).
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
even utilities whose rates do not include
fuel and purchased power adjustment
clauses nevertheless typically must
charge their retail customers cost-based
rates, which means that their energy
charges will vary from one rate case to
the next as their fuel and purchased
power costs vary from year to year.
These mechanisms for ensuring that
utility rates vary with the cost of energy
result in variances in utility energy rates
that are similar to the variance in QF
energy rates for those states that elect a
Competitive Price option (either a
Market Hub Price or a Combined Cycle
Price) for as-available avoided cost rates.
123. Finally, although we are
sympathetic to the claims of certain QFs
that they provide non-energy benefits
(such as environmental benefits, waste
reduction benefits, and economic
development benefits) that are not
reflected in avoided cost rates, PURPA
section 210(b) prohibits the Commission
from requiring QF rates to be set above
full avoided costs. Because the
Commission already requires states to
set QF rates at full avoided costs, it is
barred from requiring QF rates set
higher than that based on the nonenergy benefits that QFs may also
provide. However, nothing in PURPA,
the PURPA Regulations as they
currently exist, or this final rule would
prevent states from rewarding QFs for
such non-energy benefits so long as that
is done outside of PURPA, such as is
now done for renewable energy credits
(RECs) to compensate QFs for providing
unique environmental or other nonPURPA benefits.190 We address in the
sections below each type of competitive
price that could be used as an
acceptable energy avoided cost.
3. LMP as a Permissible Rate for Certain
As-Available Avoided Cost Rates
a. NOPR Proposal
124. The Commission proposed to
revise 18 CFR 292.304 to add
subsections (b)(6) and (e)(1). In
combination, these subsections would
permit a state the flexibility to set the
as-available energy rate paid to a QF by
an electric utility located in an RTO/ISO
at LMPs calculated at the time of
delivery.
125. The Commission explained that
RTO/ISO markets calculate a LMP at
each location on the RTO/ISOcontrolled grid, and that all sellers
receive the LMP for their location and
all buyers pay the market clearing price
190 See, e.g., American Ref-Fuel Co., 105 FERC
¶ 61,004, at PP 22–24 (2003), denying reh’g, 107
FERC ¶ 61,016 at PP 12, 15–16 (2004), dismissing
pet. for review sub nom. Xcel Energy Servs. Inc. v.
FERC, 407 F.3d 1242 (D.C. Cir. 2005).
PO 00000
Frm 00020
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
for their location. The Commission
further recognized that LMPs reflect the
true marginal cost of production, taking
into account all physical system
constraints, and these prices would
fully compensate all resources for the
variable cost of providing service,191
and explained that prices in such an
LMP-based rate structure are designed
to reflect the least-cost of meeting an
incremental megawatt-hour of demand
at each location on the grid in each
period, and thus such prices can vary
based on location and time.192
126. The Commission therefore
preliminarily found that LMP is an
accurate measure of avoided costs.
Unlike, for example, average systemwide cost measures of avoided cost used
by many states, LMP could provide an
accurate measure of the varying actual
avoided costs for each receipt point on
an electric utility’s system where the
utility receives power from QFs; LMP is
the per MWh cost of obtaining
incremental supplies at each point.
Further, the Commission explained that
these prices are not rigid, long-lasting
prices as tends to be the case currently
for administratively-determined avoided
costs, but prices that are calculated
daily (for the day-ahead markets) and/or
every five minutes (for real-time
markets) and they vary to reflect
changing system conditions (e.g., they
tend to rise as demand increases and the
system operator dispatches increasingly
expensive supplies to meet that higher
demand). In addition, the Commission
observed that LMPs, in contrast to the
administrative pricing methodologies
used to set as-available QF rates by
many states, could promote the more
efficient use of the transmission grid,
promote the use of the lowest-cost
generation, and provide for transparent
price signals.193 Finally, the
Commission also noted that Congress,
through enactment of PURPA section
210(m), appears to have recognized that
RTO/ISO LMP pricing provides
sufficient encouragement for QFs.
127. The Commission requested
comment on whether the real-time
prices established in the CAISOadministered Energy Imbalance Market
191 Offer Caps in Mkts Operated by Reg’l
Transmission Orgs. and Independent Sys.
Operators, Order No. 831, 157 FERC ¶ 61,115, at P
7 (2016), order on reh’g and clarification, Order No.
831–A, 161 FERC ¶ 61,156 (2017).
192 Sacramento Mun. Util. Dist. v. FERC, 616 F.3d
520, 524 (D.C. Cir. 2010) (SMUD); see also FERC v.
Elec. Power Supply Ass’n, 136 S. Ct. 760, 768–69
(2016) (describing how LMP is typically calculated).
193 See, e.g., Cal. Indep. Sys. Operator Corp., 105
FERC ¶ 61,140, at PP 48–50 (2003); cf. Price
Formation in Energy and Ancillary Servs. Mkts
Operated by Reg’l Transmission Orgs. and Indep.
Sys. Operators, 153 FERC ¶ 61,221, at P 2.
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
(EIM) 194 are similar for these purposes
to the LMP in RTOs/ISOs. In this regard,
the Commission requested comment on
whether ‘‘prices developed in the EIM
similarly ‘reflect the least-cost of
meeting an incremental megawatt-hour
of demand at each location on the grid,’
as the Commission has found to be the
case with LMP rates.’’ 195
128. The Commission understood that
some states already use LMP to establish
avoided cost energy rates under the
existing PURPA Regulations.196 The
Commission thus proposed also to
clarify that, while a state in the past may
have been able to conclude that LMP
was an appropriate measure of the
energy component of avoided costs,197 a
state would, under the proposal in the
NOPR, be able to adopt LMP as a per se
appropriate measure of the as-available
energy component of avoided costs.198
194 The Commission noted that, by seeking
comment regarding the Western EIM prices, the
Commission did not mean to imply that real-time
energy prices established by CAISO within its
balancing authority area do not already satisfy the
requirement for setting as-available QF rates.
195 NOPR, 168 FERC 61,184 at P 47 (quoting
SMUD, 616 F.3d at 524). Use of real time prices in
the Western EIM was addressed at the Technical
Conference, but only in the context of whether that
market could satisfy the requirements for
termination of the mandatory purchase obligation
under PURPA section 210(m)(1)(C). See
Supplemental Notice of Technical Conference,
Implementation Issues Under the Public Utility
Regulatory Policies Act of 1978, Docket No. AD16–
16–000 (May 9, 2016). The Commission here
requested comments on whether it would be
appropriate to use the Western EIM price to develop
an as-available energy rate.
196 See Exelon Wind 1, LLC, 140 FERC ¶ 61,152,
at P 11, reconsideration denied, 155 FERC ¶ 61,066
(2016) (recognizing that the Texas Public Utility
Commission has permitted Southwestern Public
Service Company to set avoided costs at LMP); Xcel
Energy Services Inc., Request for Reconsideration,
Docket No. EL12–80–001, at 13 & n.23 (filed Sept.
27, 2012) (stating that Maryland, New Jersey, North
Carolina, Virginia, Connecticut, New Hampshire,
Kentucky, and Michigan have set avoided costs at
LMP).
197 See 18 CFR 292.304(e).
198 The Commission recognized in the NOPR that
this proposal could be seen as a departure from the
Commission’s statement in Exelon Wind 1, LLC, 140
FERC ¶ 61,152 at P 52, reconsideration denied, 155
FERC ¶ 61,066 (‘‘The problem with the
methodology proposed by [Southwestern Public
Service Company] and adopted by the Texas
Commission is that it is based on the price that a
QF would have been paid had it sold its energy
directly in the [Energy Imbalance Service] Market,
instead of using a methodology of calculating what
the costs to the utility would have been for selfsupplied, or purchased, energy ‘but for’ the
presence of the QF or QFs in the markets, as
required by the Commission’s regulations.’’). The
Commission has since found that this statement
was overtaken by events, namely SPP’s evolution
from an energy imbalance service market into an
Integrated Marketplace, with day-ahead and realtime energy and operating reserve markets and the
Texas Commission’s approving a separate request
from Southwestern Public Service Company to
substitute LMP for Locational Imbalance Prices in
calculating avoided costs. Exelon Wind 1, LLC, 155
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
b. Comments
i. Comments in Opposition
129. Several commenters oppose the
NOPR’s LMP proposal.199 American
Biogas asserts that, by definition, LMP
rates assume that generating facilities
are receiving other compensation to
fund their operations and that the
marginal rate reflects only the value of
the energy. American Biogas asserts that
LMP ignores biogas facilities’ unique
municipal infrastructure role and
multiple benefits to the community.200
Covanta argues that avoided costs paid
to small baseload QFs should
incorporate all long-run avoided costs
for capacity and energy and include
other externalities such as the value of
renewable baseload energy, greenhouse
gas mitigation, landfill diversion,
reliable and resilient power and other
benefits of small baseload QFs.201
Biological Diversity argues that LMP
pricing ignores variability across the
country and is inappropriate in regions
like the Southeast which lack RTOs and
ISOs and are instead still dominated by
vertically-integrated monopolies.202
130. CA Cogeneration argues that
LMP may not represent a truly
competitive price for electricity because,
in California, the majority of supply is
through bilateral contracts, not through
competitive bidding in the market. CA
Cogeneration states that rooftop solar
distorts LMP by reducing load and not
bidding in its full long-term marginal
cost.203 CA Cogeneration states that
LMPs can be well below the operating
cost of conventional generation and
combined heat and power, and even
negative, especially when there is an
abundance of procured resources such
as hydro, solar, and wind.204 CA
Cogeneration asserts that combined heat
and power can survive only if: (1) Fixed
FERC ¶ 61,066 at P 11. The Commission also has
acknowledged that, if adopted in a final rule, the
reasoning in the NOPR supported a departure from
precedent. See Cal. Pub. Utils. Comm’n v. FERC,
879 F.3d 966, 977 (9th Cir. 2018) (‘‘When an agency
changes policy, the requirement that it provide a
reasoned explanation for its action demands, at a
minimum, that the agency ‘display awareness that
it is changing position.’’’) (citing FCC v. Fox
Television Stations, Inc., 556 U.S. 502, 515 (2009)).
199 Biogas Comments at 2; Covanta Comments at
8–9; Biological Diversity Comments at 8–9; CA
Cogeneration Comments at 8–9; ELCON Comments
at 23–25; ENGIE Comments at 4; New England
Small Hydro Comments at 8–11; NIPPC, CREA,
REC, and OSEIA Comments at 53–60; Public
Interest Organizations Comments at 52–64; Union
of Concerned Scientists Comments at 4–9;
Southeast Public Interest Organizations Comments
at 21–25.
200 Biogas Comments at 2.
201 Covanta Comments at 8.
202 Biological Diversity Comments at 8–9.
203 CA Cogeneration Comments at 8–9.
204 Id.
PO 00000
Frm 00021
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
54657
capacity prices are sufficiently high to
cover the energy price risk; (2) the
market price reflects the full cost of
contracted power and includes all
sources of supply; or (3) 18 CFR
292.304(f)(1) is modified to provide QF
operations first priority, except in
special circumstances related to
reliability.205
131. ELCON argues that allowing
utilities to use LMP and other
competitive market prices would allow
states to ignore long-standing factors
established by Commission regulation
in determining the avoided cost rates,
including: (1) Availability of capacity or
energy from a QF during the system
daily and seasonal peak periods; (2)
dispatchability and reliability; (3) the
relationship of the availability of energy
or capacity from the QF to the ability of
the utility to avoid costs; (4) costs or
savings from variations in line losses;
and (5) application of technologyspecific avoided cost rates.206 ENGIE
argues that allowing states to set energy
rates at LMP, while also allowing them
to set capacity rates at zero if it is
determined that a utility has no need for
capacity, could allow traditional
utilities to corner the market on
capacity, leaving smaller independent
QFs to fill energy-only contracts at
LMP.207
132. New England Small Hydro states
that the Commission has not supported
the NOPR’s assertion that LMP is an
accurate measure of avoided costs
because the NOPR: (1) Inappropriately
relies on the Energy Policy Act of 2005’s
changes in PURPA section 210(m) to
support its proposed changes to
calculation of the avoided cost rate; (2)
ignores the costs that the utility pays to
procure power (i.e., RFPs, other power
contracts, planned retirements); and (3)
ignores the fact that LMP and the
default service rates that exist in ISO–
NE-based states are quite different.208 In
addition, New England Hydro states
that, for the avoided cost calculation,
the appropriate LMP is the day-ahead
LMP, not the real-time LMP, because
utilities primarily purchase energy in
the day-ahead market pursuant to
bilateral contracts or RFPs, not in the
real-time market.209 New England
Hydro also believes that utilities or state
regulatory bodies should be required to
establish and maintain long-term
avoided energy forecasts upon which
205 Id.
206 ELCON
Comments at 23–24.
Comments at 4.
208 New England Small Hydro Comments at 8–10.
209 Id. at 10.
207 ENGIE
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
54658
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
QF PURPA power purchase rates would
be based.210
133. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA
claim that LMPs only promote more
efficient use of the transmission grid in
the short-term because factors such as
temporary outages, equipment failures,
weather extremes, and the like can
cause LMPs to spike, but these have no
impact on long-term transmission
availability.211 NIPPC, CREA, REC, and
OSEIA believe that, while LMPs are a
useful tool for developers to identify
points on the grid where transmission is
relatively more or less congested,
developers have strong incentives to
avoid congestion, and they will
generally be guided to areas of low
congestion during the transmission
interconnection process, whether or not
they face LMP-based contract prices.
NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA claim
that if transmission constraints prevent
a generator from delivering power to a
specific node, the LMP at that node
cannot be an appropriate measure of
costs avoided by purchase of power
from that generator. NIPPC, CREA, REC,
and OSEIA argue that LMP or Western
EIM prices at the time of delivery are
not a true measure of the long-term
avoided costs of incumbent utilities
unless those utilities are relying on
those markets as a means to obtain longterm resources.212
134. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA
assert that the NOPR proposal fails to
recognize: (1) the Commission’s struggle
to develop effective capacity markets in
the RTO/ISO regions; (2) the fact that
the merchant generation model is now
in serious question; and (3) that the
Commission’s claim that Congress
endorsed the use of LMP to set avoided
cost rates by adoption of section 210(m)
cannot be squared with the plain
language of the statute.213 NIPPC, CREA,
REC, and OSEIA argue that there is
substantial evidence that LMP prices are
distorted by certain practices, such as
zero-cost bids, so that plants operate
uneconomically.214 NIPPC, CREA, REC,
and OSEIA further maintain that the
2000–01 California market
demonstrated that these volatile shortterm markets can reach extreme and
unpredictable highs under stress
conditions.215
135. Similarly, Public Interest
Organizations cite to studies by the
210 Id.
at 11.
CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at
211 NIPPC,
57–59.
212 Id. at 55 (citing Exelon Wind I, 140 FERC
¶ 61,152 at P 52).
213 Id. at 57–59.
214 Id. at 55.
215 Id. at 57.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
Sierra Club 216 and Bloomberg New
Energy Finance,217 for the proposition
that the use of LMP as the QF price
discriminates against QFs where utilityowned generation and non-QF
generators are not limited to the LMP for
recovery of their costs, and where
utilities depress LMP through
uneconomic dispatch of their own
generation facilities.218 Union of
Concerned Scientists states that LMPs
are not an accurate measure of avoided
costs and should not be used to set QF
rates because the practice of providing
utility-owned generation with out-ofmarket cost-recovery in areas like MISO,
PJM, SPP, the SERC Reliability
Corporation, and the Western Electricity
Coordinating Council suppresses the
clearing prices in the markets where this
is allowed.219
136. Southeast Public Interest
Organizations argue that the NOPR’s
proposed avoided cost methodology
does not take into account: (1) Longterm or seasonal purchases made from
third parties or affiliates; (2)
adjustments for transmission and
distribution losses; (3) capacity
deferrals; (4) avoided environmental
compliance costs; or (5) a QF’s
dispatchability.220 Southeast Public
Interest Organizations state that LMPbased rates for QFs in Virginia have
enticed little-to-no QF development in
Virginia.221 Southeast Public Interest
Organizations urge the Commission
either to rescind the NOPR’s LMP
provisions or at least to implement this
provision on a case-by-case basis.222
(a) Utilizing Western EIM To Establish
Avoided Costs
137. Solar Energy Industries argues
that, because as-available QF resources
are not eligible to participate in the
Western EIM (also known as the CAISO
EIM), either directly or through the
purchasing utility, it would be
inappropriate to use the Western EIM
price as a proxy because that market
does not factor in the participation of
the QF resource.223 ELCON asserts that
216 Public Interest Organizations Comments at 53–
56 (citing Jeremy Fisher, Sierra Club, Playing with
Other People’s Money, How Non-Economic Coal
Operations Distort Energy Markets, Sierra Club, Oct.
2019, at 4).
217 Id. at 57 (citing William Nelson & Sophia Liu,
Half of U.S. Coal Fleet on Shaky Economic Footing;
Coal Plant Operating Margins Nationwide,
Bloomberg New Energy Finance, March 26, 2018).
218 Id. at 52–64.
219 Union of Concerned Scientists Comments at
3–8.
220 Southeast Public Interest Organizations
Comments at 22.
221 Id. at 23.
222 Id. at 24.
223 Solar Energy Industries Comments at 27.
PO 00000
Frm 00022
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
the Western EIM is not a complete
measure of avoided energy costs
because the Western EIM merely covers
imbalance conditions, and therefore
does not capture the vast majority of
unit commitment and dispatch
scheduling cost parameters.224 Union of
Concerned Scientists asserts that
allowing a state to adopt real-time prices
established in the Western EIM as an
accurate measure of avoided costs will
be discriminatory.225
ii. Comments in Support
138. Several commenters support the
Commission’s proposal to permit a state
the flexibility to use LMPs to set the asavailable energy rate paid to a QF by an
electric utility located in an RTO/
ISO.226
139. CA Utilities state that the NOPR’s
LMP proposal is a return to the
Commission’s policy as expressed in
Winding Creek,227 and will facilitate
payments to QFs that more accurately
represent a utility’s actual avoided
costs. CA Utilities assert that the
NOPR’s LMP proposal affirms that a
formula energy price contract complies
with PURPA if coupled with a fixed
capacity price. CA Utilities state that a
formula energy price contract will have
the additional benefit of avoiding the
need to develop and administer a new
PURPA contract.228
140. NRECA supports the
Commission’s proposal because many
utilities that participate in the RTO/ISO
markets offer the entirety of their
generation into the market, and
purchase all of their requirements to
serve load from that market, at LMP
prices.229
141. The Pennsylvania Commission
supports the NOPR proposal because
LMP prices vary through the day based
on changing system conditions, such as
changes in electricity demand, supply,
congestion, and line losses. The
Pennsylvania Commission asserts that,
because some utilities in Pennsylvania
224 ELCON
Comments at 24.
of Concerned Scientists Comments at 9.
226 APPA Comments at 11; Arizona Public Service
Comments at 5; CA Utilities Comments at 17; Conn.
Authority Comments at 13; DTE Electric Comments
at 4; EEI Comments at 22–24; Comments at 4–5;
Idaho Commission Comments at 3–4; Indiana
Municipal Comments at 5; Kentucky Commission
Comments at 4–5; NorthWestern Comments at 4–7;
NRECA Comments at 6–7; Ohio Commission Energy
Advocate Comments at 4–5; Pennsylvania
Commission Comments at 7–9; South Dakota
Commission Comments at 2; US Chamber of
Commerce Comments at 4; We Stand Comments at
1; Xcel Comments at 5.
227 CA Utilities Comments at 15–17 (citing
Winding Creek Solar LLC, 151 FERC ¶ 61,103,
at P 6 (2015)).
228 Id. at 17.
229 NRECA Comments at 6.
225 Union
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
(and other states) have already
incorporated LMP elements in their asavailable energy rates, a corresponding
revision to the Commission’s
regulations that incorporates such
practices and harmonizes state and
federal regulations would bring greater
predictability to suppliers, electric
utilities and customers.230
142. The Ohio Commission Energy
Advocate believes that, in the parts of
the country with organized nodal
wholesale electricity markets, LMP is an
appropriate and fair means by which to
calculate avoided costs because
electricity supply and demand must be
balanced in real time. The Ohio
Commission Energy Advocate notes that
Ohio has nodal LMPs that reflect the
true value of energy at the place and the
time it is produced or delivered, and
this value can change dramatically, even
within a day or an hour. The Ohio
Commission Energy Advocate
concludes that reflecting the dynamic
nature of electricity pricing in avoided
cost calculations will send the most
accurate price signals to QFs and will
appropriately and fairly value the
energy they produce.231
143. The South Dakota Commission
supports using LMP for certain asavailable QF energy sales because using
LMP will increase states’ flexibility. The
South Dakota Commission regulates six
vertically integrated electric utilities,
five of which are RTO members, and
five of which are multi-jurisdictional.232
144. Xcel submits that compensating
QFs based on LMPs at the time of
delivery will not impair QFs’ ability to
obtain financing because other factors
can drive the ability to obtain financing,
including other project options,
location, size, interconnection costs,
experience of the developer, current
economic conditions, creditworthiness
of the developer, economies of scale,
and other factors. Xcel states that some
resource specific information generally
suggests that the right project in the
right location can obtain financing if the
project receives hourly payment based
on LMPs.233
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
(a) Utilizing Western EIM To Establish
Avoided Costs
145. NorthWestern and EIM Entities
agree that the Western EIM real-time
prices are similar to LMPs and reflect
the least cost of meeting an incremental
megawatt-hour of demand at each
230 Pennsylvania
231 Ohio
Commission Comments at 7–8.
Commission Energy Advocate Comments
at 4–5.
232 South Dakota Commission Comments at 2.
233 Xcel Comments at 5–7.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
location on the grid.234 Xcel asserts that
prices in the Western EIM are calculated
using the same methodology as LMPs
because, in both cases, units are
dispatched on a least-cost basis that
respects applicable transmission
constraints. Xcel requests that the
Commission allow avoided costs to be
based on Western EIM prices at the time
of delivery absent a showing that prices
would be suppressed in comparison to
an LMP-style-market.235 Arizona Public
Service states that it is a participant in
the Western EIM, and requests that
states be given flexibility to set the asavailable energy rate to be paid to a QF
by an electric utility that participates in
the Western EIM at the LMP.236
iii. Comments in Support With
Requested Modifications/Clarifications
146. APPA urges the Commission to
clarify that nothing in the proposed rule
is intended to call into question state
regulatory authorities’ existing
implementation of PURPA’s avoided
cost requirements, such as their existing
use of LMP.237
147. Industrial Energy Consumers do
not object to the use of LMP as the
avoided cost rate for electric utilities’
purchases of QF energy in RTO/ISO
regions,238 but they maintain that in
non-RTO/ISO regions, there must be
assurance that utilities’ self-builds face
the same market risk exposure as
QFs.239
148. The Kentucky Commission
supports the NOPR’s LMP proposal but
prefers that the Commission in the final
rule allow states to determine whether
the LMP calculation should use the
generator LMP or the load LMP on a
case-by-case basis.240
149. Solar Energy Industries assert
that, where the purchasing utility has
demonstrated that it procures its
marginal energy from an LMP market,
the utility may use the LMP price as a
proxy for avoided energy costs
calculated at the time the obligation is
incurred, so long as there are published
prices at the location.241 Solar Energy
Industries request that the Commission
make clear that: (1) The flexibility to set
QF payment rates for as-available energy
at the applicable LMP requires an on-the
record determination that the
purchasing utility procures incremental
energy from the identified LMP market
234 EIM Entities Comments at 2–3, 7–13;
NorthWestern Comments at 4–5.
235 Xcel Comments at 7–8.
236 Arizona Public Service Comments at 5–6.
237 APPA Comments at 9.
238 Industrial Energy Consumers Comments at 11.
239 Id. at 12.
240 Kentucky Commission Comments at 4–5.
241 Solar Energy Industries Comments at 25–26.
PO 00000
Frm 00023
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
54659
at those prices; (2) payments based on
an LMP do not relieve the purchasing
utility of the requirement to compensate
the QF for any values in addition to
electricity (e.g., renewable energy
credits, frequency response capabilities,
pro-rated capacity value, etc.); and (3)
the state’s flexibility to allow utilities to
set QF payment rates for as-available
energy at the applicable LMP does not
in any way limit QFs’ rights to establish
a LEO or contract for a longer-term sale
at fixed, full avoided costs.242
150. NorthWestern believes that asavailable rates based on LMPs should
accurately capture current events
impacting prices, including times when
there is a high saturation of energy
available causing prices to be negative.
However, NorthWestern believes that it
is appropriate to deduct from the
avoided cost rate the cost for ancillary
services to balance and integrate energy
resources.243
c. Commission Determination
151. We affirm with one modification
the NOPR proposal to allow LMP to be
used as a measure of as-available energy
avoided costs for electric utilities
located in RTO/ISO markets for the
reasons set forth in the NOPR 244 and
those provided by various commenters.
152. We recognize that an LMP
selected by a state to set a purchasing
utility’s avoided energy cost component
might not always reflect a purchasing
utility’s actual avoided energy costs.
Accordingly, we find that it is
appropriate to modify the option for a
state to set avoided energy costs using
LMP from a per se appropriate measure
of avoided cost to a rebuttable
presumption that LMP is an appropriate
means to determine avoided cost. While
a state could rely on the presumption,
an aggrieved entity (such as a QF) may
attempt to rebut the presumption that
LMP reflects the purchasing electric
utility’s avoided costs. The aggrieved
entity would be able to challenge the
state’s decision to rely on LMP in the
appropriate forum, which could include
any one or more of the following: (1)
Initiating or participating in proceedings
before the relevant state commission or
governing body; (2) filing for judicial
review of any state regulatory
proceeding in state court (under PURPA
section 210(g)); or, alternatively (3))
filing a petition for enforcement against
the state at the Commission and, if the
Commission declines to act, later filing
a petition against the state in U.S.
242 Id.
at 27–28.
243 NorthWestern
244 NOPR,
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
Comments at 4–5.
168 FERC ¶ 61,184 at PP 44–45.
02SER2
54660
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
district court (under PURPA section
210(h)(2)(B)).245
153. Commenters have not persuaded
us that LMP may not presumptively
reflect a purchasing electric utility’s
avoided energy costs. LMP sets dayahead and real-time energy prices
through competitive auctions in RTOs/
ISOs that optimally dispatch resources
to balance supply and demand, while
taking into account actual system
conditions including congestion on the
transmission system. We continue to
find that: (1) LMPs reflect the true
marginal cost of production of energy,
taking into account all physical system
constraints; (2) these prices would fully
compensate all resources for their
variable cost of providing service; (3)
LMP prices are designed to reflect the
least-cost of meeting an incremental
megawatt-hour of demand at each
location on the grid, and thus prices
vary based on location and time; and (4)
unlike average system-wide cost
measures of the avoided energy cost
used by many states, LMP should
provide a more accurate measure of the
varying actual avoided energy costs,
hour by hour, for each receipt point on
an electric utility’s system where the
utility receives power from QFs.246
154. Various commenters have
provided additional reasons for
supporting the NOPR proposal
concerning LMP. NRECA explains that
LMP rates for energy are appropriate
because many utilities that participate
in the RTO/ISO markets offer the
entirety of their generation into the
market at LMP prices and buy all of
their load requirements from the market
at LMP prices.247 This scenario
described by NRECA is a common one,
and it demonstrates that the market
itself, with its LMP pricing, can be the
electric utility resource that would be
displaced by a QF purchase.
Furthermore, as argued by Pennsylvania
Commission, because some utilities in
Pennsylvania and other states have
already incorporated LMP in their asavailable energy rates, a corresponding
revision to the Commission’s
regulations that incorporates such
practices and harmonizes state and
federal regulations would bring greater
245 See Policy Statement Regarding the
Commission’s Enforcement Role Under Section 210
of the Public Utility Regulatory Policies Act of 1978,
23 FERC ¶ 61,304.
246 See NOPR, 168 FERC ¶ 61,184 at PP 44–45
(citing SMUD, 616 F.3d at 524; FERC v. Elec. Power
Supply Ass’n, 136 S. Ct. at 768–69 (describing how
LMP is typically calculated); Order No. 831, 157
FERC ¶ 61,115, at P 7, order on reh’g and
clarification, Order No. 831–A, 161 FERC ¶ 61,156).
247 NRECA Comments at 6.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
predictability to suppliers, electric
utilities and customers.248
i. Arguments Against the NOPR
Proposal
155. Commenters have not offered
persuasive arguments for rejecting the
use of LMP for avoided cost energy rate
determination. We disagree with the
argument made by Union of Concerned
Scientists,249 NIPPC, CREA, REC, and
OSEIA,250 and Public Interest
Organizations 251 that LMP should not
be used as a measure of avoided energy
costs because LMP prices are depressed
in many markets where self-scheduling
rights and state cost-recovery
mechanisms for fuel and operating costs
create the opportunity for market
participation at a loss. We recognize
that, all other things being equal, selfscheduling of resources may impact
market clearing prices. This potential
price effect, however, does not mean
that the LMP is not an accurate measure
of avoided energy costs. The
Commission’s regulations, using
language from PURPA section 210(d),
define avoided costs as ‘‘the incremental
costs to an electric utility of electric
energy or capacity or both which, but
for the purchase from the qualifying
facility or qualifying facilities, such
electric utility would generate for itself
or purchase from another source.’’ 252
156. In organized wholesale electric
market areas, the electric utility
purchases that would be displaced by
QF purchases would, as NRECA
explains, in all likelihood be priced at
the relevant LMP. These LMPs are
impacted by many factors, such as selfscheduling, generator outages, and
transmission outages, that may result in
LMPs that are lower or higher than they
might otherwise have been. Thus, while
self-scheduling or other factors may
impact LMPs, in any case, an electric
utility’s purchases during periods when
these price impacts are occurring would
be made at the resulting LMPs, whatever
those LMPs may be. Therefore, LMPs
meet the Commission’s long-standing
definition of avoided costs for a
purchasing electric utility, even if they
happen to reflect price impacts from
self-scheduling or other factors.
157. Furthermore, while commenters
discuss the possibility that utilityowned coal-fired resources are selfscheduling only because retail
248 Pennsylvania
249 Union
Commission Comments at 7–8.
of Concerned Scientists Comments at
3–8.
250 NIPPC,
CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at
ratepayers are subsidizing such
activities, even if such claims were true
they would not alter the above analysis.
The LMPs that result from a market that
includes self-scheduled resources still
represent the price of purchases in the
market that would be displaced by the
QF purchase.
158. In addition, we reject the related
request for clarification made by Solar
Energy Industries,253 i.e., that the
flexibility to set QF payments for asavailable energy at the applicable LMP
should require an on-the-record
determination that the purchasing
utility procures incremental energy from
the identified LMP market at those
prices. Unless an aggrieved entity seeks
to rebut this presumption in a state
avoided cost adjudication, rulemaking,
legislative determination, or other
proceeding, that state would not need to
make such an on-the-record
determination before it decides to use
LMP.
159. Entities may seek to rebut the
presumption in particular cases, as
described earlier, and whether the
utility actually procures energy from the
identified LMP market or from resources
with prices tied to the identified LMP
may be a relevant factor in such rebuttal
arguments. Consistent with the reasons
described above for why there should be
such a rebuttable presumption in favor
of LMP, this delineation of rights
appropriately places the initial burden
on entities seeking to rebut the
presumption, rather than on the states
who wish to rely on LMP for setting
avoided cost rates for as-available
energy. The Commission could consider
such issues if and when they may arise
in individual cases appropriately
brought to the Commission, including
whether the state has adequately
justified its use of that rebuttable
presumption.
160. We reject the arguments made by
NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA that,
more generally, prices for long-term QF
contracts should be set by reference to
long-term price indices or other
indicators that genuinely reflect the
long-term costs of generation avoided by
the purchasing utility.254 This final rule
only addresses as-available energy, and
as-available energy prices by definition
are short term, as explained below in
Section IV.B.7.c.
161. We also reject the arguments
made by NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA
that, while the NOPR is correct that
LMPs are intended to promote more
efficient use of the transmission grid,
52.
251 Public
Interest Organizations Comments 52–
64.
Energy Industry Comments at 27–28.
CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at
254 NIPPC,
252 18
PO 00000
253 Solar
CFR 292.101(b)(6) (emphasis added).
Frm 00024
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
53.
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
that is true only in the short term since
factors such as temporary outages,
equipment failures, weather extremes,
and the like can cause LMPs to spike,
but these have no impact on long-term
transmission availability. LMPs promote
efficient use of the transmission grid in
the long term as well as the short term.
Persistence of significant price
separation between different LMP nodes
provides an indication of the value of
various possible transmission system
upgrades and can show transparently
how system efficiencies may be
improved by such transmission system
upgrades. Developers may have some
incentive to avoid congestion without
LMPs, but LMPs provide an important
price signal as to how economic or
uneconomic a particular production site
may be. In any event, the potential for
more efficient use of the transmission
grid is merely an additional benefit of
using LMP for avoided energy cost
determinations. Our adoption of LMP as
a measure of avoided energy costs in the
RTO/ISO markets is based principally
on the fact that, in RTO/ISO markets,
LMP accurately represents the
purchasing electric utility’s avoided
energy cost at the time the energy is
delivered, for the reasons described
earlier.
162. We also are not persuaded by
arguments that, if transmission
constraints prevent a generator from
delivering power to a specific node, the
LMP at that node cannot be an
appropriate measure of costs avoided by
purchase of power from that generator.
As discussed above, an avoided cost rate
should reflect not only the cost of
energy that was avoided by the
purchasing electric utility, but also the
cost to deliver the QF energy to the
purchasing electric utility’s load, such
that the total cost avoided is reflected in
the rate. In an RTO/ISO market, a state
appropriately is entitled to consider
whether the cost of delivery from the QF
node to the load node (including any
redispatch costs necessary to facilitate
such delivery over a system that is
otherwise constrained between those
nodes) should be reflected in the LMP
at the QF supply node. In instances
commenters refer to where transmission
constraints prevent a generator from
delivering power to a specific node, we
disagree that such delivery is actually
‘‘prevented.’’ Rather, redispatch of
system resources would be necessary to
facilitate the delivery, and the
respective LMPs reflect those redispatch
costs.
163. We also reject the argument
made by NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA
that the 2000–01 California market
demonstrated that volatile short-term
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
markets can reach extreme and
unpredictable highs under stress
conditions.255 First we note that, in the
wake of the 2000–2001 California
energy crisis, all RTO/ISO markets
developed more comprehensive ex ante
market power mitigation measures than
existed in CAISO at that time, including
offer caps and reference level
replacement offers, meant in part to
moderate such extremes.256 In any
event, any price volatility that may
currently exist in LMP markets,
regardless of the reason for the price
volatility, and regardless of whether the
volatility causes LMPs to be lower or
higher, nevertheless accurately
represents the avoided cost of the
purchasing electric utilities in those
markets in those hours, as explained
elsewhere in this final rule.
164. Finally, we remain convinced
that Congress recognized that RTO/ISO
LMP pricing provides sufficient
encouragement for QFs through the
enactment of PURPA section 210(m)
with its directive that, essentially, the
mandatory purchase obligation can be
lifted upon QFs having nondiscriminatory access to RTO/ISO
markets. As noted earlier, however, our
decision to grant states the flexibility to
rely on a rebuttable presumption that
RTO/ISO LMP pricing is an appropriate
measure of avoided energy costs (and
thus set as-available energy rates in
reliance on LMPs) reflects our view that,
in RTO/ISO markets, as a general matter
LMP indeed accurately represents the
purchasing electric utility’s avoided
energy costs.
165. We also disagree with
ELCON’s 257 argument that LMP should
not be used to measure avoided costs
because that would allow states to
ignore long-standing factors established
by the Commission that should be used
to determine avoided costs. The factors
referenced by ELCON are relevant to the
traditional administrative determination
of avoided cost, and our revisions to the
regulations preserve these factors for
that purpose and for avoided capacity
costs. If a state chooses instead to rely
on LMP to set avoided energy cost rates,
then it will necessarily not be using
those administrative means of
255 NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at
57. Curiously, these commenters here essentially
take the position that higher LMPs and resulting
higher avoided cost energy rates, which would
normally seem to be beneficial to QFs, are instead
now anathema.
256 See generally Wholesale Competition in
Regions with Organized Elec. Mkts., Order No. 719,
125 FERC ¶ 61,071 (2008), order on reh’g, Order No.
719–A, 128 FERC ¶ 61,059, order on reh’g, Order
No. 719–B, 129 FERC ¶ 61,252 (2009).
257 ELCON Comments at 23–24.
PO 00000
Frm 00025
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
54661
determining avoided costs, and these
factors thus will not be relevant.
166. We are not persuaded by the
arguments of various commenters that
LMP cannot be used for avoided cost
rates because it ignores the unique
municipal infrastructure role and the
multiple benefits of the community of
biogas facilities,258 including the value
of renewable baseload energy,
greenhouse gas mitigation, landfill
diversion, reliable and resilient power
and other benefits of small baseload
QFs.259 PURPA frames the
determination of QF rates in terms of
avoided cost and does not authorize the
Commission in determining QF rates,
particularly as-available energy rates, to
consider non-energy-related factors such
as a generator’s unique municipal
infrastructure role, greenhouse gas
mitigation, and landfill diversion.
167. We also are not persuaded by the
argument of CA Cogeneration that LMP
may not represent a truly competitive
price for electricity in California since
the majority of California supply is
through bilateral contracts, not through
competitive bidding in the market, and
that other factors also distort LMP such
as roof top solar. CA Cogeneration, in
essence, objects to the state of
California’s decision to award preferred
resource status to some resources, such
as solar and wind, and not others, such
as cogeneration. These are procurement
decisions made at the state level in
connection with resource planning and
retail ratemaking. Even if those
decisions impact the resulting LMPs, as
CA Cogeneration claims, that impact
would not invalidate the arguments
made above for why LMP is
presumptively an appropriate measure
of as-available energy avoided costs in
RTO/ISO markets. The aggrieved entity
would be able to challenge the state’s
decision to rely on LMP in the
appropriate forum, which could include
any one or more of the following: (1)
Initiating or participating in proceedings
before the relevant state commission or
governing body; (2) filing for judicial
review of any state regulatory
proceeding in state court (under PURPA
section 210(g)); or, alternatively (3)
filing a petition for enforcement against
the state at the Commission and, if the
Commission declines to act, later filing
a petition against the state in U.S.
district court (under PURPA section
210(h)(2)(B)).260
258 Biogas
Comments at 2.
Comments at 8.
260 See Policy Statement Regarding the
Commission’s Enforcement Role Under Section 210
of the Public Utility Regulatory Policies Act of 1978,
23 FERC ¶ 61,304.
259 Covanta
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
54662
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
168. We reject the argument made by
New England Small Hydro that the
Commission has not supported its view
that LMP is an accurate measure of
avoided costs since LMP ignores the
costs that the utility pays to procure
power, including through competitive
solicitations, other power contracts,
planned retirements and other factors
that are considered in a utility’s longterm plans; and ignores the fact that
LMP and the default service rates that
exist in ISO–NE-based states are quite
different.261 The costs that a purchasing
utility pays to procure power, including
through competitive solicitations, other
power contracts, planned retirements
and other factors that are considered in
a utility’s long-term plans may be
relevant to the utility’s purchase of
capacity using long-term contracts, but
not to the determination of the proper
as-available energy avoided cost rate to
be paid to QFs, which rates will
necessarily vary as system conditions
vary over time, as reflected by variances
in LMP over time. The fact that LMP
and the default service rates that exist
in ISO–NE-based states may diverge is
to be expected because the latter, unlike
the as-available energy rates charged by
QFs in RTO/ISO markets that LMP is
being used to price, normally include
transmission and distribution costs (and
possibly firm supplier capacity costs)
necessary to ensure that firm supply is
continually available to residential
customers.262 While utilities or state
regulatory authorities continue to have
the authority to establish and maintain
long-term avoided energy forecasts upon
which QF PURPA power purchase rates
may be based, and to recognize the
actual future energy costs incorporated
in new power contracts that are being
261 New
England Small Hydro Comments at 8–10.
ISO–NE, Transmission, Markets, and
Services Tariff, LMPs and Real-Time Reserve
Clearing Prices Calculation, § III.2.5 (describing
how nodal real-time prices are calculated in ISO–
NE at each node using energy offers and bids,
transmission constraints, and other factors) with
National Grid, Investigation as to the Propriety of
Proposed Tariff Changes, Docket No. DPU 18–150,
Exh. NG–HSG–1, Gorman Test. 3:18–4:6 (Nov. 15,
2018), https://fileservice.eea.comacloud.net/
FileService.Api/file/FileRoom/10043215 (‘‘The
Company’s filing is based on its investments and
costs incurred to provide distribution service to its
customers. An [Allocated Cost of Service Study]
directly assigns or allocates each element of the
revenue requirement, including plant and other
investments, operating expenses, depreciation and
taxes, among the rate classes, in order to determine
the costs of providing service to each rate class.
Each element of the total revenue requirement is
analyzed and assigned to or allocated among the
rate classes, so the utility can establish rates that,
subject to assumptions such as kilowatt-hour
(‘kWh’) delivery volumes and the number of
customers, provide it with a fair opportunity to
recover its costs and to earn an appropriate
return.’’).
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
262 Compare
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
signed by New England utilities,
elsewhere in this final rule the
Commission explains why the use of
variable prices can be appropriate for
long-term energy contracts.
169. We are not persuaded by the
argument of Southeast Public Interest
Organizations that the NOPR does not
establish a framework for just and
reasonable and nondiscriminatory rates
because the proposed avoided cost
methodology does not take into account
any long-term or seasonal purchases
made from third parties or affiliates,
adjustments for transmission and
distribution losses, capacity deferrals,
avoided environmental compliance
costs, or dispatchability of the QF.263
LMP pricing, in fact, does reflect
transmission and distribution losses.
The other factors that the Southeast
Public Interest Organizations mention
here, such as environmental compliance
costs, dispatchability, long-term or
seasonal purchases and capacity
deferrals, are factors that are more
applicable to the pricing of capacity and
long-term contracts, not the pricing of
as-available energy, which is what the
Commission’s NOPR proposal as
adopted in this final rule addresses.
170. The Commission rejects the
argument made by Biological
Diversity 264 that LMP pricing ignores
the variability of conditions across the
country. LMP prices by definition vary
as supply, demand, and system
conditions change across the country. In
any event, the Commission agrees that
LMP pricing would not currently be
applicable in regions like the Southeast
that lack RTOs and ISOs and thus that
do not use LMP.
171. We further reject the argument
made by ENGIE that allowing states to
set energy rates using LMPs combined
with the ability to set capacity rates at
zero if it is determined that a utility has
no need for capacity has the potential to
allow traditional utilities to corner the
market on capacity, leaving smaller
independent QFs to provide only
energy-only service.265 PURPA does not
direct the Commission to guarantee that
QF sales make up some specified share
of utilities’ capacity needs nor does it
require that each QF receive
compensation for providing capacity.
PURPA instead focuses on the
purchasing electric utility’s avoided
costs and provides that the Commission
cannot require that prices charged by a
QF exceed the purchasing electric
utility’s avoided cost, if a purchasing
263 Southeast Public Interest Organizations
Comments at 22.
264 Biological Diversity Comments at 8–9.
265 ENGIE Comments at 4.
PO 00000
Frm 00026
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
electric utility has no need for
additional capacity (and thus the
purchasing utility’s avoided cost for
capacity would be zero),266 the only
service that QFs (and other suppliers)
would need to provide that utility is
energy. However, a utility’s ability to
‘‘corner the market’’ on capacity
depends not uniquely on the pricing of
QF sales to the utility, but on a host of
factors including the utility’s analysis of
its need for capacity and, without a
specific inquiry into the circumstances
of each utility, it cannot be concluded
that any utility’s decision will always be
deficient or that it has been adversely
and inappropriately affected by the
Commission’s action here.
172. Several commenters maintain
that reliance on LMP will make it
difficult for QFs to obtain financing.267
This argument is addressed below in
section IV.B.7 of this final rule.
ii. Requests for Modification or
Clarification of the NOPR
173. We will not provide the
clarifications requested by New England
Small Hydro that the Commission
require the use of the day-ahead LMP
for QF rates set at LMP, or Southeast
Public Interest Organizations’ request to
require the use of real-time LMP rather
than average LMP. States that choose to
use LMP will determine the LMP most
representative of the avoided cost of the
relevant purchasing utility.
174. While the Kentucky Commission
requests that the Commission allow the
use of the LMP at a delivery (load) node
rather than a receipt (generator or QF)
node, we find that this decision should
be made by the state as it determines
which particular LMP best reflects the
avoided cost of the purchasing electric
utility.
175. We grant APPA’s request for
clarification that, while the NOPR
provides greater clarity as to states’
entitlement to rely on competitively-set
prices as a measure of avoided cost
rates, nothing in the final rule is
intended to call into question any
particular state’s existing
implementation of PURPA’s avoided
cost requirements, such as their existing
use of LMP.268 While in the past a state
266 See, e.g., NOPR, 168 FERC ¶ 61,184 at P 33
n.58; see also City of Ketchikan, Alaska, 94 FERC
¶ 61,293 at 62,061 (2001) (‘‘[A]voided cost rates
need not include the cost for capacity in the event
that the utility’s demand (or need) for capacity is
zero. That is, when the demand for capacity is zero,
the cost for capacity may also be zero.’’).
267 Biogas Comments at 2; BluEarth Renewables
Comments at 2; Biological Diversity at 8; Covanta
Comments at 9; Distributed Sun Comments at 1–2;
New England Small Hydro Comments at 10; NIPPC,
CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 53.
268 APPA Comments at 9.
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
may have been able to conclude that
LMP was an appropriate measure of the
avoided cost for energy, a state can now
also rely on a rebuttable presumption
that LMP is an appropriate measure of
the as-available avoided cost for energy
to be used in determining a QF’s asavailable avoided cost energy rate.
176. We provide the following
clarification in response to the Solar
Energy Industries’ request that the
Commission make clear that payments
based on LMP do not relieve the
purchasing utility of the requirement to
compensate the QF for any values in
addition to electricity (e.g., RECs, etc.),
and that the state’s flexibility to allow
utilities to set QF payment rates for asavailable energy at the applicable LMP
does not in any way limit QFs’ rights to
establish a LEO or contract for a longerterm sale at fixed, full avoided costs.269
In Windham Solar LLC,270 the
Commission summarized its precedent
concerning RECs. The Commission
stated that the states have the authority
to determine who owns RECs in the
initial instance and how they are
transferred, and that the automatic
transfer of RECs within a sale of power
at wholesale must find its authority in
state law, not PURPA. But the
Commission also held that a state may
not assign ownership of RECs to utilities
based on a logic that the avoided cost
rates in PURPA contracts already
compensate QFs for RECs in addition to
compensating QFs for energy and
capacity, because under PURPA the
avoided cost rates are, in fact,
compensation just for energy and
capacity.271 We see no reason to disturb
that precedent in this final rule. With
regard to the right of QFs to establish a
LEO, that right is neither limited nor
expanded by a state’s choice of LMP as
the measure of avoided costs for energy.
iii. Western EIM
177. We hereby find that the Western
EIM prices, like other LMP prices, may
presumptively be used as a measure of
as-available energy avoided costs for
utilities able to participate in the
Western EIM market. As Xcel points
out, ‘‘prices in the EIM are calculated
using the same methodology as LMPs’’
since, ‘‘in both cases, units are
dispatched on a least-cost basis that
respects applicable transmission
constraints (i.e., congestion),’’ and ‘‘[t]he
formula for price calculation involves
determination of the system marginal
energy cost, which is the cost of
providing the next increment of energy
Energy Industry Comments at 27–28.
FERC ¶ 61,042 (2016).
271 Id. P 4.
to the system, minus congestion costs,
minus losses, and, in some cases, minus
the cost of carbon.’’ 272 As with LMP,
these Western EIM price components
presumptively reflect the avoided cost
of as-available energy incurred by
purchasing electric utilities that are able
to participate in the Western EIM
region.
178. We reject arguments that Western
EIM prices should not be used to
establish as-available avoided cost
energy rates for sales by QFs. With
respect to the unit commitment and
dispatch scheduling cost parameters
ELCON refers to, it is true that the
Western EIM is a real-time imbalance
market built on a decentralized unit
commitment that may not result in
exactly the same real-time dispatch and
LMP as would result from an RTO
market with centralized day-ahead unit
commitment and co-optimized energy
and reserves. Nonetheless, Western EIM
prices represent quite precisely the
avoided cost of as-available energy for
utilities operating in that market
structure since those prices show the
cost of obtaining an additional unit of
energy at any particular place and time.
With regard to the argument of Union of
Concerned Scientists concerning the
cost recovery mechanisms available to
utility-owned and -affiliated
generation,273 as discussed above with
respect to the rebuttable presumption
that LMP may be used for avoided cost
rate determination, we do not find these
unproven allegations of use of retail cost
recovery mechanisms to subsidize
wholesale RTO/ISO market
participation at a loss sufficient to make
a blanket finding prohibiting the use of
Western EIM prices to set as-available
avoided cost energy rates for sales by
QFs.
179. With regard to the argument
concerning the ability to participate in
the Western EIM raised by Solar Energy
Industries,274 for PURPA rate purposes,
it is not relevant whether QFs are able
to participate in the Western EIM. The
rates at issue here are intended, per the
statute, to reflect the costs of alternative
electric energy that the purchasing
utility is avoiding. In this context, all
that matters is whether the Western
EIM’s prices accurately reflect a
purchasing electric utility’s avoided
costs for energy. Thus, as long as the
purchasing electric utility is able to
participate in the Western EIM, a
rebuttable presumption should apply
that Western EIM prices reflect the
269 Solar
272 Xcel
270 156
273 Union
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
Comments at 7–8.
of Concerned Scientists Comments at 9.
274 Solar Energy Industry Comments at 27.
PO 00000
Frm 00027
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
54663
purchasing electric utility’s avoided
costs for energy.
4. Use of Market Hub Prices as a
Permissible Rate for Certain AsAvailable QF Energy Sales
a. NOPR Proposal
180. In the NOPR, the Commission
recognized that competitive bilateral
energy markets have arisen outside of
the RTO/ISO energy markets.
Particularly in the Western United
States, price hubs such as the MidColumbia (Mid-C) and Palo Verde hubs
are liquid markets with prices the
Commission has recognized as
representing competitive market prices
at those hubs.275 For the same reasons
that LMPs could represent an
appropriate avoided cost energy rate for
QFs selling to electric utilities located in
RTO/ISO markets, the Commission
proposed to find that liquid market hubs
can represent appropriate rates for QFs
selling to electric utilities located
outside of RTO/ISO markets. Like LMP,
liquid market hubs would rely on
competition to derive an avoided cost.
From a price determination perspective,
liquid market hub prices differ from
LMP mainly in that they measure price
at only one or a few points, whereas
RTOs/ISOs derive unique LMPs for all
receipt and delivery points on a specific
area of the system.276
181. Consequently, the Commission
proposed in the NOPR to revise the
PURPA Regulations in 18 CFR 292.304
to add a subsection (b)(7) which, in
combination with new subsection (e)(1),
would permit a state to set the asavailable energy rate paid to a QF by
electric utilities located outside of RTO/
ISO markets at energy rates established
at liquid market hubs. The Commission
proposed to define Market Hub Prices as
prices determined at a liquid market
hub to which the purchasing electric
utility has reasonable access. States
electing to set QF energy rates using a
Market Hub Price also would identify
the particular market hub used to set the
275 NOPR, 168 FERC ¶ 61,184 at P 52 (citing Price
Discovery in Nat. Gas and Elec. Mkts., 109 FERC
¶ 61,184, at P 66 (2004) (approving the use of
published prices at market hubs with sufficient
liquidity to set prices charged in tariffs); El Paso
Elec. Co., 148 FERC ¶ 61,051, at P 7 (2014)
(approving the use of the Palo Verde price to set
imbalance charges); Idaho Power Co., 121 FERC
¶ 61,181 at P 27 (2007) (approving use of MidColumbia prices to set energy imbalance charge);
PacifiCorp, 95 FERC ¶ 61,467, at 62,676 (2001)
(approving setting energy imbalance rate at average
of four market hub prices); Pinnacle West Energy
Corp., 92 FERC ¶ 61,248, at 61,791 (2000) (accepting
the use of the Palo Verde price to set prices for
affiliate transactions because the Palo Verde Index
is a recognized market hub with competitive
prices)).
276 NOPR, 168 FERC ¶ 61,184 at P 53.
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
54664
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
price. Such determination would
require the state to find that the prices
at such hub are competitive prices that
reflect the costs an electric utility would
avoid but for the purchase from the
QF.277
b. Comments
i. Comments in Support
182. Arizona Public Service and El
Paso Electric state that the Palo Verde/
Hassayampa hub represents a regional
liquid market hub that could be used to
set as-available energy avoided costs.278
Portland General likewise asserts that
the Mid-C price hub should be approved
as appropriate for use in establishing asavailable energy avoided costs.279
183. Xcel provides two additional
factors to support the liquid market hub
proposal. First, Xcel cites to the 2018
State of the Market report issued by the
Commission’s Office of Enforcement’s
Division of Energy Market Oversight,
which states that trading hub prices
generally align with energy prices
associated with competitive, marketbased sales. Second, Xcel cites to
wholesale power sales contracts
providing for the purchase of excess
energy based on a combination of dayahead prices at Palo Verde and at Four
Corners, which Xcel asserts
demonstrates that prices at Palo Verde
and Four Corners are reasonably
representative of the value of energy.280
ii. Comments in Opposition
184. Several commenters argue that
liquid market hubs are short-term spot
markets and do not represent long-term
energy rates or the other costs associated
with that energy including, but not
limited to, congestion, transmission,
and capacity costs.281 Other
commenters express concern with
setting QF prices at short-term liquid
hub prices while allowing utilities to
rate base and recover their long-term
investments.282
185. Public Interest Organizations
assert that the liquid market hub
proposal is discriminatory because nonQF generators are not limited to the
liquid market hub price and utilities
can, and regularly do, pay effective
prices for energy that exceed the price
determined by regional trading.283
Union of Concerned Scientists similarly
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
277 Id.
P 56.
278 Arizona Public Service Comments at 6–8; El
Paso Electric Comments at 2–3.
279 Portland General Comments at 6–7.
280 Xcel Comments at 8.
281 IdaHydro Comments at 11; Southeast Public
Interest Organizations Comments at 19.
282 IdaHydro Comments at 11; Industrial Energy
Consumers Comments at 12–13.
283 Public Interest Organizations Comments at 64.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
asserts that liquid market hub prices are
distorted by the participation of
integrated utilities that submit bids
below their total costs.284
186. Industrial Energy Consumers
oppose the liquid market hub pricing
proposal because such markets are not
sufficiently competitive,
nondiscriminatory, and transparent to
be used as the basis for calculating a
utility’s avoided cost payment.285
Industrial Energy Consumers urge the
Commission not to assume that noncompetitive markets are, in fact,
competitive.286 Southeast Public
Interest Organizations state that no
southeast state could credibly identify a
particular market hub that is reasonably
accessible and has competitive prices
that actually relate to the costs an
electric utility would avoid but for the
purchase from the QF.287 Southeast
Public Interest Organizations also assert
that the liquid market hub proposal
does not require states to determine
whether liquid market hub prices
represent a utility’s avoided costs, and
therefore the proposal would allow
liquid market hubs to set avoided
energy prices even when they do not
represent avoided energy costs.288
187. ELCON asserts that a liquid
regional hub does not necessarily imply
liquidity at a more granular level.289
According to ELCON, the basis spread
resulting from transmission congestion
outside of RTO/ISOs is often opaque in
real time and poorly documented in
hindsight, and this is a clear indication
that discriminatory treatment and
barriers to the bulk transmission system
persist under current conditions outside
of RTO/ISOs.290 ELCON states that for
these and other reasons, bilateral
markets alone are insufficient to serve as
complete avoided cost measures.291
188. Allco states that prices at liquid
market hubs would suffer from
shortcomings with respect to small QFs
connected to the distribution system,
because purchases from such QFs also
allow the purchasing utility to avoid
transmission costs, including line
losses.292
iii. Commission Determination
189. We adopt the proposal in the
NOPR to give the states flexibility to set
as-available avoided cost energy rates
284 Union
of Concerned Scientists Comments at 8.
Energy Consumers Comments at 12.
285 Industrial
286 Id.
287 Southeast Public Interest Organizations
Comments at 18.
288 Id. at 19.
289 ELCON Comments at 25.
290 Id.
291 Id.
292 Allco Comments at 7–8.
PO 00000
Frm 00028
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
using prices from a liquid market hub to
which the purchasing electric utility has
reasonable access. For the reasons
explained in the NOPR, we find that
liquid market hubs can represent
appropriate as-available avoided cost
energy rates for QFs selling to electric
utilities located outside of RTO/ISO
markets. However, as the Commission
also found in the NOPR, before relying
on prices from liquid market hubs, a
state must find that the liquid market
hub price in question represents the
purchasing utility’s avoided cost for asavailable energy.293
190. Examples of factors a state
reasonably could consider in making
this determination (in addition to the
core finding that the liquid market hub
represents the purchasing utility’s
avoided cost for as-available energy) are:
(1) Whether the hub is sufficiently
liquid that prices at the hub represent a
competitive price; 294 (2) whether the
prices developed at the hub are
sufficiently transparent; (3) whether the
electric utility has the ability to deliver
power from such hub to its load, even
if its load is not directly connected to
the hub; and (4) whether the hub
represents an appropriate market to
derive an energy price for the electric
utility’s purchases from the relevant
QFs given the electric utility’s physical
proximity to the hub. These factors are
not intended to be exhaustive, and
states reasonably could consider other
factors in identifying a relevant liquid
market hub for setting as-available QF
energy rates.
191. In order for prices at market hubs
to represent a purchasing electric
utility’s avoided costs, the market hub
price may need to be subject to
adjustments to account for transmission
costs the electric utility would incur
before such prices could serve as a
factor in determining appropriate QF
rates.295 In addition, market prices in a
region may be determined based on a
formula that includes adjustments to the
market hub price or that incorporates
prices at more than one market hub
located in the region, when such prices
represent standard pricing practice in
the region where the purchasing electric
utility is located.296 Such adjustments
may be necessary to ensure that the
293 See
NOPR, 168 FERC ¶ 61,184 at PP 53, 56.
considering whether a hub is sufficiently
liquid, states could, for example, consider such
factors as those identified by the Commission in
Price Discovery in Nat. Gas and Elec. Mkts., 109
FERC ¶ 61,184, at P 66.
295 Other adjustments also may be necessary in
other situations in order for the adjusted hub price
to reasonably reflect the purchasing electric utility’s
avoided cost.
296 NOPR, 168 FERC ¶ 61,184 at P 58.
294 In
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
competitive market price reflects a
purchasing utility’s actual avoided costs
for as-available energy.
192. Arguments regarding the shortterm nature of liquid market hubs and
claims that use of such prices is
discriminatory are addressed in Section
IV.B.2 above.
193. We will not address in this final
rule arguments about whether particular
market hubs should be found to
represent avoided costs or, to the
contrary, that particular market hubs
may be too illiquid or insufficiently
granular, or that prices at particular
market hubs may not reflect avoided
costs. We are not making any
determination in this final rule that the
prices at any specific market hub do or
do not represent the avoided costs of
any specific utility. Rather, we are
allowing the states the flexibility to rely
on prices at liquid market hubs to set asavailable avoided cost energy rates for
QF sales in regions outside RTO/ISO
markets upon a state finding that it is
appropriate to do so given the specific
circumstances governing a particular
market hub and the purchasing utility
involved. The aggrieved entity would be
able to challenge the state’s decision to
use a liquid market hub price in the
appropriate forum, which could include
any one or more of the following: (1)
Initiating or participating in proceedings
before the relevant state commission or
governing body; (2) filing for judicial
review of any state regulatory
proceeding in state court (under PURPA
section 210(g)); or, alternatively (3)
filing a petition for enforcement against
the state at the Commission and, if the
Commission declines to act, later filing
a petition against the state in U.S.
district court (under PURPA section
210(h)(2)(B)).297
194. With respect to Southeast Public
Interest Organizations’ assertion that the
liquid market hub proposal in the NOPR
does not require states to determine
whether liquid market hub prices
represent a utility’s avoided costs, the
Commission intended to impose such a
requirement as a prerequisite before a
liquid market hub may be relied on as
a measure of a purchasing utility’s
avoided cost of as-available energy.
However, we acknowledge that the
regulatory text in the NOPR was
ambiguous in that regard. Therefore, the
regulatory text of 18 CFR
292.304(b)(7)(i) in the final rule has
been revised to make this more clear.
297 See Policy Statement Regarding the
Commission’s Enforcement Role Under Section 210
of the Public Utility Regulatory Policies Act of 1978,
23 FERC ¶ 61,304.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
c. Proposed Modifications
i. Comments
195. APPA requests that the
Commission clarify that, in addition to
liquid market hubs, as-available energy
avoided costs could be determined
based on prices of comparable
competitive quality.298 APPA states that
amending the proposed regulation in
this fashion would also enable utilities
proximate to (or embedded within)
RTO/ISO markets to reference prices in
those markets as viable alternatives in
establishing avoided costs.299
196. The California Commission
requests that the Commission clarify
that states previously were permitted to
use liquid market hub prices under the
current PURPA Regulations and that the
proposed revisions simply codify and
confirm the validity of this past
practice.300 The California Commission
and Massachusetts DPU further request
that the proposed rules be modified to
permit states to use competitive prices
to set both energy and capacity costs,
and to not be limited to using such
mechanisms only for as-available energy
prices.301
197. EEI notes that some states may be
located in regions with access to more
than one market hub and those states
should have the flexibility to use an
average of market hub prices or develop
a formula correlated to the appropriate
market hubs to develop the electric
utility’s avoided cost.302 EEI notes that
this proposal is not new, but its
inclusion in the Commission’s
regulations will provide certainty to
states.303
198. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA
assert that the liquid market hub
proposal should not be adopted without
making significant changes.304 For
example, they argue, only long-term
contract prices reported at market hubs
should be used.305 Even with respect to
market-hub prices for long-term
contracts, they assert that the
Commission should include safeguards
to ensure that prices are set based on
liquid trading with a sufficient number
of competitors to assure effective price
discovery, that prices are not subject to
manipulation, and that reported price
indices are accurate and not subject to
mis-reporting or other forms of
54665
manipulation.306 Finally, they argue
that the Commission should require
avoided costs to include the costs of
transmission to and from such hubs
except in cases where the utility’s
system directly interconnects with that
hub.307 Resources for the Future makes
similar arguments.308
199. In contrast, NorthWestern asserts
that liquid market hub prices should be
adjusted downward by a transmission
differential to reflect the cost of getting
energy from the market to load.309
NorthWestern states that reliance on the
market hub to establish avoided costs
only remains a valid option if the prices
are less than what it would cost a utility
to build a resource to supply its
customers’ needs.310
ii. Commission Determination
200. We clarify that, in adopting a
rule allowing states to use liquid market
hubs to determine as-available avoided
energy costs, we are not finding that the
use of liquid market hubs for this
purpose prior to the issuance of this
final rule was not permitted. Depending
on the specific circumstances, a state
may appropriately have determined,
prior to the final rule, that a liquid
market hub price represented a
purchasing utility’s as-available avoided
energy cost. After the effective date of
this final rule, an aggrieved entity may
seek review of a state’s determination to
use liquid market hubs in the
appropriate forum.311
201. We confirm that: (1) States
located in regions with access to more
than one market hub have the flexibility
to use an appropriate average of market
hub prices or to develop an appropriate
formula that relies on data from relevant
market hubs to develop an electric
utility’s as-available avoided energy
cost, so long as doing so yields a price
that accurately reflects the purchasing
electric utility’s as-available avoided
energy cost; 312 (2) states must
determine that a liquid market hub is
sufficiently liquid that its prices
represent a competitive price; 313 and (3)
the market hub price may need to be
subject to adjustments to account for
transmission costs the electric utility
would incur.314
306 Id.
307 Id.
298 APPA
Comments at 13.
299 Id. at 13.
300 California Commission Comments at 24.
301 California Comments at 25; Massachusetts
DPU Comments at 8–10.
302 EEI Comments at 26.
303 Id. at 27.
304 NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at
60.
305 Id.
PO 00000
Frm 00029
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
308 Resources
for the Future Comments at 8.
Comments at 5.
309 NorthWestern
310 Id.
311 See Policy Statement Regarding the
Commission’s Enforcement Role Under Section 210
of the Public Utility Regulatory Policies Act of 1978,
23 FERC ¶ 61,304.
312 NOPR, 168 FERC ¶ 61,184 at P 58.
313 Id. P 57.
314 Id. P 58.
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
54666
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
202. Finally, we find that the general
ruling requested by APPA regarding the
use of ‘‘prices of comparable
competitive quality’’ to set as-available
avoided cost rates is beyond the scope
of this rulemaking in that here we were
proposing only particular discrete
changes to our regulations for setting asavailable avoided cost energy rates
charged by QFs.
5. Use of Formulas Based on Natural
Gas Prices To Establish a Permissible
Rate for Certain As-Available QF Energy
Sales
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
a. NOPR Proposal
203. The Commission observed in the
NOPR that, in regions where there are
no RTOs/ISO or liquid market hubs, the
price of electricity generated by efficient
combined-cycle natural gas generation
facilities would appear to represent a
reasonable measure of a competitive
energy price.315
204. The Commission therefore
proposed to revise the PURPA
Regulations in 18 CFR 292.304 to add a
subsection (b)(7) which, in combination
with new subsection (e)(1), would
permit a state to set the as-available
energy rate paid to a QF by electric
utilities located outside of RTO/ISO
markets at Combined Cycle Prices,
defined as a formula rate established by
the state using published natural gas
price indices and a proxy heat rate for
an efficient natural gas combined-cycle
generating facility. The state would
need to determine that the resulting
Combined Cycle Price represents an
appropriate approximation of the
purchasing electric utility’s avoided
costs. This determination would involve
consideration of such factors as, for
example: (1) Whether the cost of energy
from an efficient natural gas combinedcycle generating facility represents a
reasonable approximation of a
competitive price in the purchasing
electric utility’s region; (2) whether
natural gas priced in accordance with a
particular proposed natural gas price
index would be available in the relevant
market; (3) whether there should be an
adjustment to the natural gas price to
appropriately reflect the cost of
transporting natural gas to the relevant
market; and (4) whether the proxy heat
rate used in the formula should be
updated regularly to reflect
improvements in generation technology.
The Commission described the above
factors as not exhaustive and proposed
providing states the flexibility to apply
315 Id.
P 59.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
other factors that also might be
appropriate for consideration.316
205. The Commission stated that
natural gas price indices coupled with
the heat rate of an efficient natural gas
combined-cycle generating facility may
be a reasonably accurate measure of
avoided cost, at least in those markets
where natural gas-fired resources are
commonly the marginal units. In such
markets, the Commission stated that it
would expect that new supplies of
energy would need to be offered at a
price equal to or less than the
incremental cost of using these efficient
gas units in order to displace them
economically. Thus, the Commission
found preliminarily that using natural
gas price indices and the heat rate of an
efficient combined-cycle natural gas
generating facility to establish an
avoided cost energy rate relies on
competitive market forces, in this case
competitive forces in natural gas
markets for the fuel used by natural gas
combined-cycle generating facilities that
the purchasing electric utility, but for
the purchase from the QF, would
generate itself or purchase from another
source.317
b. Comments
206. Several entities oppose the
NOPR’s Combined Cycle Prices
proposal.318 Allco asserts that this is
exactly the type of administrative
avoided cost determination about which
NARUC and utilities have
complained.319 Allco also argues that
the only reason for including the
Combined Cycle Prices proposal in the
Commission’s regulations is to create a
menu of prices from which a state
commission or unregulated utility can
choose the lowest price, which Allco
claims would not encourage QF
generation, and would be inconsistent
with the rules of economic dispatch and
the language of PURPA.320 Public
Interest Organizations argue that the
Combined Cycle Price proposal is
discriminatory to QFs for all the same
reasons that restricting QF rates to LMP
is discriminatory (i.e., because utilities
can, and allegedly do, pay effective
prices for energy that exceed the
calculation from natural gas prices and
assumed combined cycle heat rates).321
316 Id.
317 Id.
P 54.
Comments at 8; BluEarth Comments at
1–2; ELCON Comments at 25–26; Industrial Energy
Consumers Comments at 10–11; Public Interest
Organizations Comments at 64; R Street Comments
at 5; Southeast Public Interest Organizations
Comments at 19–20.
319 Allco Comments at 8.
320 Id.
321 Public Interest Organizations Comments at 64.
318 Allco
PO 00000
Frm 00030
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
Southeast Public Interest Organizations
argue that the Combined Cycle Prices
proposal does not require states to
include variable O&M costs in the proxy
combined cycle plant or an adjustment
for natural gas transportation, even
though a utility-owned combined cycle
gas plant would be allowed to recover
both types of costs.322
207. In contrast, R Street opposes the
proposal because using natural gas
combined cycle plants as the basis for
QF rates in non-RTO/ISO regions could
lead to the overpayment of a QF. R
Street argues that regions without
organized wholesale markets should
instead price QF rates at the lowest cost
resource based on an administratively
determined avoidable cost.323
208. Similarly, ELCON argues that the
proposal is complicated by the fact that
natural gas units are not always
marginal, especially in exportconstrained subregions when
renewables output is high. ELCON
believes this proposal would be subject
to extensive forecasting error, and
therefore argues that careful assessment
should precede its adoption.324
209. Other entities support the
NOPR’s Combined Cycle Price
proposal.325 The California Commission
and EEI argue that states already had
this flexibility under the current
regulations, and request that the
Commission acknowledge this fact in a
final rule.326 Similarly, other supporters
of the Combined Cycle Price proposal
argue that states should have the ability
to develop as-available energy price
formulas based on technologies other
than combine cycle gas plants, if doing
so would more accurately reflect the
relevant purchasing utility’s avoided
cost.327
210. El Paso Electric argues that: (1)
The gas index price should be adjusted
to account for the basis differential
between the price at the natural gas hub
and the price of natural gas in or near
the utility’s service area; and (2) states
should be allowed to update the formula
periodically to reflect improved
322 Southeast Public Interest Organizations
Comments at 19–20.
323 R Street Comments at 5.
324 ELCON Comments at 26.
325 APPA Comments at 12–13; Arizona Public
Service Comments at 6; California Commission
Comments at 23; Chamber of Commerce Comments
at 4; Duke Energy Comments at 9–10; EEI
Comments at 27; El Paso Electric Comments at 3;
Idaho Commission Comments at 3; Southern
Comments at 9.
326 California Commission Comments at 23; EEI
Comments at 27–28.
327 APPA Comments at 13; Duke Energy
Comments at 10; EEI Comments at 27; Idaho
Commission Comments at 3; Southern Comments at
9–11.
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
utility’s avoided cost for as-available
energy.
214. While some commenters
c. Commission Determination
requested that we expand the proposed
211. We adopt the NOPR proposal to
regulation explicitly to include
revise 18 CFR 292.304 to add a
technologies other than combined cycle
subsection (b)(7) which, in combination natural gas generating facilities, we
with new subsection (e)(1), would
decline to do so for two reasons. First,
permit a state to set the as-available
as already mentioned, the current
energy rate paid to a QF by electric
regulations are already flexible enough
utilities located outside of RTO/ISO
to accommodate states calculating
markets at Combined Cycle Prices,
avoided costs based on the cost of the
defined as a formula rate established by generating units or technology that
the state using published natural gas
accurately reflects the relevant
price indices and a proxy heat rate for
purchasing utility’s avoided cost.331
an efficient natural gas combined-cycle
Second, this proposal focused
generating facility. We also clarify that
specifically on combined cycle
the formulas used to set as-available
technology, as opposed to other
energy rates based on natural gas prices
generating technologies, because
should include recovery of variable
combined cycle generation makes up
O&M costs.
such a large portion of the nation’s
212. While some commenters oppose
generation fleet.332 This relative
allowing states to use Combined Cycle
ubiquity, coupled with the fact that
Prices (or other competitive prices) to
combined cycle natural gas generation
set avoided energy cost rates, states
facilities are often the marginal units in
already had the flexibility to determine
many regions, justifies an elevated
avoided costs in this manner under the
profile in the PURPA Regulations for
current regulations, as the California
combined cycle technology compared to
329
Commission and EEI observe.
If
other technologies. This final rule does
Combined Cycle Prices accurately
not foreclose other technologies from
represent a particular purchasing
being used for avoided cost
utility’s avoided energy costs, their use
determination, upon an appropriate
would be consistent with the
finding by the state that they accurately
Commission’s existing definition of
measure a purchasing electric utility’s
avoided costs as ‘‘the incremental costs
avoided cost for as-available energy.
to an electric utility of electric energy or
215. Southeast Public Interest
capacity or both which, but for the
Organizations support their opposition
purchase from the qualifying facility or
to Combined Cycle Prices in part by
qualifying facilities, such utility would
claiming that the Commission did not
generate itself or purchase from another
specifically require states to include
330
source.’’
Furthermore, as noted above
variable O&M in the formula. We agree
in section IV.B.2, the use of competitive
that variable O&M expenses are an
market prices, including Combined
appropriate cost component of formula
Cycle Prices, to set QF rates is explicitly
rates and should be included in any
subject to the requirement that such
Combined Cycle Price formulae in order
prices are equal to the purchasing
to accurately reflect the relevant
utility’s avoided energy costs. Therefore,
purchasing electric utility’s avoided
this proposal merely codifies more
costs.
explicitly an option for determining
216. With respect to the arguments of
avoided cost rates that already existed,
Southeast Public Interest Organizations
i.e., where a state determines that a
regarding natural gas transportation
Combined Cycle Price is a measure of
costs, the regulation we adopt in this
the purchasing electric utility’s avoided final rule, 18 CFR 292.304(b)(7)(ii)(C),
cost for as-available energy.
specifically requires that states consider
213. The concerns of R Street,
whether there should be an adjustment
ELCON, and others that Combined
to the natural gas price to appropriately
Cycle Prices may not reflect a particular
purchasing electric utility’s avoided cost
331 See 18 CFR 292.101(b)(6).
are addressed by the requirement that
332 According to EIA data, the nameplate capacity
the state would need to determine that
of natural gas-fired combined cycle generation
technology, exceeds the nameplate capacity of
the Combined Cycle Price indeed
generation from any other fuel source. See EIA,
represents the purchasing electric
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
efficiencies in combined cycle
generating facilities.328
328 El
Paso Electric Comments at 3–4.
could have used any of the competitive
prices adopted in this final rule to set avoided cost
energy rates as long as such prices met, to the extent
practicable, the factors described 18 CFR
292.304(e).
330 See 18 CFR 292.101(b)(6).
329 States
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
Electric Power Annual Table 4.7.A Net Summer
Capacity of Utility Scale Units by Technology and
by State, 2018 and 2017 (Megawatts), https://
www.eia.gov/electricity/annual/html/epa_04_07_
a.html, and 4.7.C Net Summer Capacity of Utility
Scale Units Using Primarily Fossil Fuels and by
State, 2018 and 2017 (Megawatts), https://
www.eia.gov/electricity/annual/html/epa_04_07_
c.html.
PO 00000
Frm 00031
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
54667
reflect the cost of transporting natural
gas to the relevant market. As to El Paso
Electric’s arguments regarding index
price adjustments using basis
differentials, and periodic formula
updates to reflect efficiency
improvements, we note that the
revisions to the PURPA Regulations,
which we adopt in this final rule,
provide that states which choose to rely
on Combined Cycle Prices must
consider, when designing their
formulae, whether and to what extent to
include these costs, based on their
assessment of how best to identify a
relevant purchasing electric utility’s
avoided cost for as-available energy.333
6. Permitting the Energy Rate
Component of a Contract To Be Fixed at
the Time of the LEO Using Forecasted
Values of the Estimated Stream of
Market Revenues
217. The NOPR noted that, frequently,
price forecasts are available for LMPs in
RTOs/ISOs, for liquid market hubs
located outside of RTOs/ISOs, and for
natural gas pricing hubs. Accordingly,
the NOPR suggested that such forecasts
could be used to allow QFs to request
a fixed energy rate component
calculated at the time a LEO is incurred.
The Commission therefore proposed to
add a new option in 18 CFR
292.304(d)(1)(iii) permitting fixed
energy rates to be based on forecasted
estimates of the stream of revenue flows
during the term of the contract.334 In
other words, states could rely on
estimates of forecasted energy prices at
the time of delivery over the anticipated
life of the contract—such estimates are
commonly referred to as forward price
curves—to develop a fixed energy rate
component for that contract when such
estimates reflect the purchasing electric
utility’s avoided costs.
218. The NOPR stated that the fixed
energy rate component of the contract
could be a single energy rate, based on
the amortized present value of the
forecast energy prices, or it could be a
series of specified energy rates that are
different in future years (or other
periods).335 Under this proposal, the QF
would be able to establish, at the time
the LEO is incurred, the applicable
energy rate(s) for the entire term of a
contract; however, the energy rate in the
contract could be different from year-to333 See
new 18 CFR 292.304(b)(7)(ii).
168 FERC ¶ 61,184 at P 61.
335 Id. P 62 (noting that the PURPA Regulations
already require that the fixed energy rate would
need to account for the operating characteristics of
the QF, including the QF’s ability to deliver energy
during peak periods and the utility’s ability to
dispatch energy from the QF (citing 18 CFR
292.304(e)(2)).
334 NOPR,
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
54668
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
year (or some other period) and
nevertheless comply with the current
requirement in 18 CFR 292.304(d)(2)(ii)
that the energy rate be fixed for the term
of the contract.336
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
a. Comments
219. Two commenters oppose the
NOPR proposal to add a new option in
18 CFR 292.304(d)(1)(iii) permitting
fixed energy rates to be based on
forecasted estimates of the stream of
revenue flows during the life of the
contract.337 Southeast Public Interest
Organizations and Mr. Mattson state
that the NOPR proposal is a departure
from past precedent.338 Southeast
Public Interest Organizations state that
this proposal suffers the same
deficiencies as the LMP and liquid
market hub price proposals.
Furthermore, according to Southeast
Public Interest Organizations, the NOPR
provides no analysis as to how or
whether the forward price curves result
in just and reasonable and nondiscriminatory rates as required by
PURPA.339
220. Other commenters support the
NOPR proposal to add a new option in
18 CFR 292.304(d)(1)(iii) permitting
fixed energy rates to be based on
forecasted estimates of the stream of
revenue flows during the term of the
contract.340 The South Dakota
Commission and Pennsylvania
Commission state that they support the
NOPR proposal on forecasted values of
the estimated stream of revenues
because it forecasts a steady stream of
revenue and provides built-in
336 Id. (noting that this is permissible under the
Commission’s existing PURPA Regulations (citing
Windham Solar LLC, 157 FERC ¶ 61,134, at PP
5–6 (2016) (Windham Solar) (‘‘[A]lthough state
regulatory authorities cannot preclude a QF . . .
from obtaining a legally enforceable obligation with
a forecasted avoided cost rate, we remind the
parties that the Commission’s regulations allow
state regulatory authorities to consider a number of
factors in establishing an avoided cost rate. These
factors which include, among others, the
availability of capacity, the QF’s dispatchability, the
QF’s reliability, and the value of the QF’s energy
and capacity, allow state regulatory authorities to
establish lower avoided cost rates for purchases
from intermittent QFs than for purchases from firm
QFs.’’ (citing 18 CFR 292.304(e)–(f)) (footnote
omitted))).
337 Southeast Public Interest Organizations
Comments at 25; Mr. Mattson Comments at 26.
338 Southeast Public Interest Organizations
Comments at 25; Mr. Mattson Comments at 26.
339 Southeast Public Interest Organizations
Comments at 25.
340 Allco Comments at 8; APPA Comments at 14;
Arizona Public Service Comments at 2–3; Chamber
of Commerce Comments at 4–5; Connecticut
Authority at 13; Distributed Sun Comments at 2;
EEI Comments at 28–30; Idaho Commission
Comments at 4; NorthWestern Comments at 6;
NRECA Comments at 8; Pennsylvania Commission
Comments at 8; Resources for the Future Comments
at 8; South Dakota Commission Comments at 3.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
flexibility.341 According to these
commenters, the proposal also balances
the QF’s need for a steady stream of
revenue with the purchasing electric
utility’s responsibility to have a prudent
mix of supply contracts for its provider
of last resort obligations.342 The
Chamber of Commerce states that, while
future rates are not guaranteed to
materialize, the projected rates will
more accurately reflect those realized
than a single avoided cost rate set at the
inception of a QF contract.343
221. Arizona Public Service states that
it supports the proposal because it
grants states additional flexibility,
which helps protect utilities’ customers
from over-paying for generation due to
QFs need for sales guarantees and
financing.344 NRECA agrees that states
must have flexibility in determining
forecasted market prices including
appropriate discounting to ensure that
utilities and consumers are not locked
into contracts with fixed prices that are
higher than prevailing market prices.345
222. NRECA requests that the
Commission clarify proposed revisions
to 18 CFR 292.304(d)(1)(i), (ii), and (iii)
to state that an electric utility is exempt
from offering a stream of market revenue
as payment, even if there is a market
hub price that could be relevant.346 The
Connecticut Authority also suggests that
the Commission modify 18 CFR
292.304(d)(1)(ii) to specify that a state
may set a series of energy rates. For this
option, Connecticut Authority argues,
the regulatory text should provide
greater regulatory and commercial
certainty to QF developers, avoiding
disputes with distribution utilities and
states.347
223. Connecticut Authority supports
revisions to 18 CFR 292.304(d)(2)
because the rule would permit a state to
limit a QF’s option to select a preferred
energy rate methodology.348
Connecticut Authority also supports the
proposed 18 CFR 202.304(d)(iii) that
permits states to set a stated or fixed rate
for energy that is calculated using the
present value of the expected stream of
revenue from as-available energy rates
during the life of the contract or LEO.
224. EEI states that this proposal is
not novel, and as an example notes that
the Commission and a federal district
court have already found that the
Connecticut Authority could set
341 Pennsylvania Commission Comments at 8–9;
South Dakota Commission Comments at 3.
342 Pennsylvania Commission Comments at 8–9.
343 Chamber of Commerce Comments at 4–5.
344 Arizona Public Service Comments at 2–3.
345 NRECA Comments at 8.
346 Id. at 9.
347 Connecticut Authority Comments at 14.
348 Id. at 13.
PO 00000
Frm 00032
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
avoided cost rates based on a forecast of
future avoided costs.349 According to
EEI, the Commission has not ruled
either that any form of forecasting is
mandated or that any is
unacceptable.350
225. Allco states that the proposed
new option in 18 CFR 292.304(d)(1)(iii)
permitting fixed energy rates to be based
on forecasted estimates of the stream of
revenue flows during the life of the
contract is consistent with PURPA
section 210 and is already permitted.
Allco also states that forecasts need to
be non-discriminatory. According to
Allco, utilities and states frequently use
one forecast when dealing with QFs and
another when obtaining approval for
their favored projects; Allco asserts that
this practice is discriminatory.351
226. APPA states that the proposed
change is a logical extension of the
conclusion that market options are a
legitimate alternative means of
specifying avoided costs.352 Distributed
Sun states that it supports permitting
states to set fixed energy rates with
forward curves or through competitive
solicitations.353 NorthWestern supports
the proposal to permit fixed energy rates
to be on a forward price curve
developed from prices in either the
organized markets or liquid market
hubs.354
b. Commission Determination
227. We adopt the proposal to add a
new option in 18 CFR 292.304(d)(1)(iii)
permitting fixed energy rates to be based
on forecasted estimates of the stream of
revenue flows during the term of the
contract. The Commission has
previously permitted the use of this
method to establish energy and capacity
rates over the term of a contract or
LEO.355 Nevertheless, given the
flexibilities we adopt in this final rule
with respect to competitive market
prices and variable energy rates, we
clarify here that a state may use
competitive market prices and/or
variable energy rates in the context of a
more fixed estimated avoided cost
energy rate (together with a fixed
avoided capacity rate) that is
determined at the time an LEO or
contract is incurred. The fixed energy
rate component of the contract could be
349 EEI Comments at 28 (citing Allco Renewable
Energy Ltd. v. Mass. Elec. Co., 208 F. Supp. 3d. 390,
395 (D. Mass. 2016); Windham Solar, 157 FERC
¶ 61,134 at P 5.
350 EEI Comments at 28–30.
351 Allco Comments at 8.
352 APPA Comments at 14.
353 Distributed Sun Comments at 2.
354 NorthWestern Comments at 6.
355 Windham Solar, 157 FERC ¶ 61,134 at P 4
(citing 18 CFR 292.304(d)(2)).
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
a single rate, based on the amortized
present value of forecast energy prices,
or it could be a series of specified rates
that change from year-to-year (or other
periods) in future years. We also will
allow the state to establish the
applicable energy rate(s) for the QF for
the entire term or the rate may change
from year-to-year (or some other period)
of the contract at the time the LEO is
incurred.
228. Southeast Public Interest
Organizations and Mr. Mattson state
that the NOPR proposal is a departure
from past precedent. The very purpose
of a proceeding like this is to consider
changes to our regulations and our
doing so is not impermissible.
229. Southeast Public Interest
Organizations also state that the
proposal suffers the same deficiencies as
the LMP and liquid market hub pricing
proposals and that the NOPR provides
no evidence as to how or if the forward
price curves present just and reasonable
and non-discriminatory rates as
required by PURPA. Given that we find
above that LMPs and liquid market hub
prices may reflect avoided as-available
energy costs and that estimates of such
prices over the term of a contract can
therefore reflect a purchasing electric
utility’s avoided as-available costs over
time, we do not believe Southeast
Public Interest Organizations and Mr.
Mattson’s concerns are justified.
230. Although, as described below,
we allow states to require variable
avoided cost energy rates, allowing
forward price curves determined at the
time an LEO is incurred provides an
additional option for states to calculate
avoided energy costs in advance while
also using transparent metrics for those
calculations. Use of the forward price
curve does not deter the adoption of just
and reasonable and non-discriminatory
rates required by PURPA, moreover, and
insofar as we require that states
determine that the estimated stream of
revenues reflects the purchasing electric
utility’s avoided energy, such pricing is
fully consistent with the statute’s
requirements. With regard to forecasts,
we acknowledge that the forecast used
to set the avoided cost rate must
meaningfully and reasonably reflect the
utility’s avoided costs over time.356
231. We decline to modify this
proposal expressly either to permit or
prohibit a state from setting a series of
estimated avoided energy costs over
time. Each state will be required to
determine whether a particular
356 See 18 CFR 292.304(b)(5). Rates calculated at
the time of a LEO (for example, a contract) do not
violate the requirement that the rates not exceed
avoided costs if they differ from avoided costs at the
time of delivery.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
estimated stream of revenues represents
a purchasing electric utility’s avoided
costs over a specified term. Similarly, in
order to provide states flexibility to use
LMPs and other competitive market
prices to establish as-available avoided
energy costs, we will not require a state
to use this option to guarantee a stream
of revenues.
7. Providing for Variable Energy Rates in
QF Contracts
a. Background
232. As explained above, if a QF
chooses to sell energy and/or capacity
pursuant to a contract, the PURPA
Regulations currently provide the QF
the option of receiving the purchasing
electric utility’s avoided cost calculated
and fixed at the time the LEO is
incurred.357 The Commission’s
justification in Order No. 69 for
allowing QFs to fix their rate at the time
of the LEO for the entire term of a
contract was that fixing the rate
provides certainty necessary for the QF
to obtain financing.358 The Commission
stated that its regulations pertaining to
LEOs ‘‘are intended to reconcile the
requirement that the rates for purchases
equal the utilities’ avoided costs with
the need for qualifying facilities to be
able to enter contractual commitments
based, by necessity, on estimates of
future avoided costs.’’ 359 Further, the
Commission agreed with the ‘‘need for
certainty with regard to return on
investment in new technologies.’’ 360
The Commission stated its belief that
any overestimations or
underestimations ‘‘will balance out.’’ 361
233. The provision that QFs be
permitted to fix their rates for the entire
term of a contract or other LEO has
proved to be one of the most
controversial aspects of the
Commission’s PURPA Regulations.
Some commenters at the Technical
Conference submitted data indicating
that energy prices have declined in
recent years, leaving the fixed energy
portion of the QF rate, even when
levelized, well above market prices that
likely would represent the purchasing
electric utility’s actual avoided energy
costs at the time of delivery.362 Based on
357 18
CFR 292.304(d)(2)(ii).
No. 69, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 30,128 at
30,880 (justifying the rule on the basis of ‘‘the need
for certainty with regard to return on investment in
new technologies’’).
359 Id.
360 Id.
361 Id.
362 See Alliant Energy Comments, Docket No.
AD16–16–000, at 5 (Nov. 7, 2016) (‘‘Current marketbased wind prices in the Iowa region of MISO are
approximately 25 [percent] lower than the PURPA
contract obligation prices [Interstate Power and
358 Order
PO 00000
Frm 00033
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
54669
this concern, some commenters
recommended that the Commission
allow states to ‘‘price generation
[energy] from QFs at market prices, and
to update those prices regularly so that
the prices for [QFs] are not burdensome
on customer rates’’ and that the
Commission should limit avoided cost
energy rates in a LEO to no higher than
avoided cost rates at the time of
delivery.363 QFs, in turn, argued that
elimination of the option to fix QF rates
for the term of a contract would threaten
a QF’s ability to obtain financing.364
b. NOPR Proposal
234. In the NOPR, the Commission
proposed to revise 18 CFR 292.304(d) to
permit a state to limit a QF’s option to
elect to fix at the outset of a LEO the
energy rate for the entire length of its
contract or LEO, and instead allow the
state the flexibility to require QF energy
Light Company] is forced to pay for the same wind
power for long-term contracts entered into as of
June 2016. As a result, PURPA-mandated wind
power purchases associated with just one project
could cost Alliant Energy’s Iowa customers an
incremental $17.54 million above market wind
prices over the next 10 years.’’) (emphasis in
original); EEI Supplemental Comments, Docket No.
AD16–16–000, attach. A at 3–4 (June 25, 2018) (EEI
Supplemental Comments) (‘‘On August 1, 2014, a
10-year fixed price contract at the Mid-Columbia
wholesale power market trading hub was priced at
$45.87/MWh. On June 30, 2016, the same contract
was priced as $30.22/MWh, a decline of 34
[percent] in less than two years. However, over the
next 10 years, PacifiCorp has a legal obligation to
purchase 51.9 million MWhs under its PURPA
contract obligations at an average price of $59.87/
MWh. The average forward price curve for the MidColumbia trading hub during the same period is
$30.22/MWh, or 50 [percent] below the average
PURPA contract price that PacifiCorp will pay. The
additional price required under long-term fixed
contracts will cost PacifiCorp’s customers $1.5
billion above current forward market prices over the
next 10 years.’’); Comm’r Kristine Raper, Idaho
Commission Comments, Docket No. AD16–16–000,
at 3–4 (filed June 30, 2016) (‘‘Idaho Power
demonstrated that the average cost for PURPA
power since 2001 has exceed the Mid-Columbia
(Mid-C) Index Price and is projected to continue to
exceed the Mid-C price through 2032. Likewise,
PacifiCorp’s levelized avoided cost rates for 15-year
contract terms in Wyoming shows a decrease of
approximately 50 [percent] from 2011 through 2015
(from approximately $60 per megawatt-hour to less
than $30 per megawatt-hour).’’).
363 EEI Supplemental Comments, attach. A at 4;
see also Southern Company Comments, Docket No.
AD16–16–000, at 7 (filed June 30, 2016) (‘‘[T]he
avoided energy cost payment to the QF should be
based on actual avoided energy cost at the time the
QF delivers energy.’’).
364 See Technical Conference, Docket No. AD16–
16–000, Tr. 26:22–25, 27:1–3 (June 29, 2016) (filed
July 8, 2016) (Technical Conference Tr.) (Solar
Energy Industries) (‘‘The Power Purchase
Agreement is the single most important contract of
the development and financing of an energy project
that’s not owned by a utility. Without the long-term
commitment to buy the output of that agreement at
a fixed price, there is no predictable stream of
revenue. Without a predictable stream of revenues,
there is no financing. Without any financing, there
is no project.’’).
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
54670
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
rates to vary during the term of the
contract. However, under the proposed
revisions to 18 CFR 292.304(d), a QF
would continue to be entitled to a
contract with avoided capacity costs
calculated and fixed at the time the
contract or LEO is incurred. Only the
energy rate in the contract or LEO could
be required by a state to vary. Further,
the NOPR did not propose to obligate
states to require variable avoided cost
energy rates—they would retain the
ability to allow the QF’s energy rate be
fixed at the time the LEO is incurred.365
235. The Commission preliminarily
found compelling the record evidence
that overestimations have not been
adequately balanced by
underestimations in past years. Further,
it appeared to the Commission that this
trend may persist into the future with
the continuing general decline in the
cost of both wind and solar
generation.366 Consequently, the
Commission found that it may be
necessary to allow states to provide for
a variable energy rate in order to reflect
more accurately the purchasing electric
utility’s avoided costs and therefore to
satisfy the statutory requirement that QF
rates not exceed the utility’s avoided
cost and ‘‘be just and reasonable to the
electric consumers of the electric utility
and in the public interest.’’ 367
236. The Commission acknowledged
that the current PURPA Regulations
allowing a QF to fix its rates for the life
of a contract or LEO were based on the
recognition that fixed rates are
beneficial for obtaining financing for QF
projects. The Commission also
recognized that QF developers have
continued to assert that they require
fixed rates to finance new projects.
However, the Commission stated that it
did not view the proposed modification
to the PURPA Regulations as materially
affecting the ability of QFs to obtain
financing for several reasons.368
237. First, the Commission expressed
its understanding that fixed energy rates
are not generally required in the electric
industry in order for electric generation
facilities to be financed. For example,
RTO/ISO capacity markets provide only
for fixed capacity payments, leaving
365 NOPR,
168 FERC ¶ 61,184 at P 67.
P 68 (citing EIA, Today in Energy, Average
U.S. construction costs for solar and wind
continued to fall in 2016 (Aug. 8, 2018), https://
www.eia.gov/todayinenergy/detail.php?id=36813
(‘‘Based on 2016 EIA data for newly constructed
utility-scale electric generators (those with a
capacity greater than one megawatt) in the United
States, annual capacity-weighted average
construction costs for solar photovoltaic systems
and onshore wind turbines declined . . . .’’)).
367 Id. P 68 (internal quotations omitted) (citing
16 U.S.C. 824a–3(b)(1)).
368 Id. P 69.
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
366 Id.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
capacity owners to sell their energy into
the organized electric markets at LMPs
that vary based on market conditions at
the time the energy is delivered. The
Commission stated that these fixed
capacity and variable energy payments
have been sufficient to permit the
financing of significant amounts of new
capacity in the RTOs and ISOs.369
Testimony presented at the Technical
Conference similarly showed that nonQF independent power projects located
outside of RTOs enter into contracts
with fixed capacity and variable energy
prices.370 Other comments at the
Technical Conference suggested that a
fixed capacity charge likewise would be
adequate for financing a QF project.371
238. The Commission further noted
that there are financial products
available, such as contracts for
differences, which allow generation
owners to hedge their exposure to
fluctuating energy prices.372 The
Commission stated that financial
products can provide additional comfort
to lenders regarding the level of energy
rate revenues that a QF can expect from
the energy it delivers, in addition to the
fixed capacity payments the QF is
entitled to receive under its contract.373
239. The Commission also explained
that, although it may have been true at
the time the Commission promulgated
its PURPA Regulations in 1980 that QFs
needed to fix their energy rate for the
term of their contract in order to obtain
financing of their facilities, there is
evidence that this no longer is true. This
evidence comes in the form of data,
369 Id. P 70 (citing Monitoring Analytics, LLC.,
Third Quarter, 2018 State of the Market Report for
PJM, January through September, at 249, Table 5–
6 (Nov. 8, 2018), https://
www.monitoringanalytics.com/reports/PJM_State_
of_the_Market/2018/2018q3-som-pjm.pdf (over
23,000 MW of new capacity constructed in PJM
Interconnection, L.L.C. since 2007–2008; including
over 16,000 MW of new capacity added in the last
four years)).
370 Id. (citing Technical Conference Tr. at 167–69
(Southern Company) (‘‘So if we enter into a bilateral
contract with an independent power producer for
combustion turbine or combined cycle capacity, we
don’t fix the energy price. The capacity payment is
a fixed payment. That’s their fixed [stream]. The
energy price is typically indexed to the price of
natural gas.’’); id. at 178 (American Forest & Paper
Association) (‘‘Now, you sign a long-term IPP
contract. That contract [has] got a variable energy
cost in it.’’)).
371 Id. P 70 (citing Solar Energy Industries
Comments, Docket No. AD16–16–000, at 3 (filed
June 30, 2016) (‘‘Developers need rates for such
sales of energy and/or capacity to be fixed.’’)
(emphasis added)).
372 Id. P 72 (citing Elec. Storage Participation in
Mrkts. Operated by Reg’l Transmission Org. and
Independent Sys. Operators, Order No. 841, 162
FERC ¶ 61,127, at P 299 (2018) (noting that ‘‘market
participants that purchase energy from the RTO/ISO
markets . . . may enter into bilateral financial
transactions to hedge the purchase of that energy’’)).
373 Id. P 72.
PO 00000
Frm 00034
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
described below, showing that
independent generators that have not
qualified as QFs under PURPA
(including renewable resources that
could qualify as QFs but have not
sought QF status) have been able to
obtain financing for new facilities. The
Commission stated that the fact that
owners of such facilities, which do not
have recourse to the avoided cost rate
provisions of PURPA, have been able to
obtain financing for new projects is
relevant to the question of whether the
existing PURPA avoided cost
provisions—including the requirement
to enter into contracts with fixed energy
rates—are necessary for QFs to obtain
financing.374
240. For example, EIA data showed
that, since 2005, QFs have made up only
10% to 20% of all renewable resource
capacity in service in the United States,
demonstrating that most renewable
resources no longer need to rely on
PURPA avoided cost rates to sell their
output economically.375 EIA data also
showed that net generation of energy by
non-utility owned renewable resources
in the United States escalated from 51.7
terawatt hours (TWh) in 2005 when
EPAct 2005 was passed, to 340 TWh in
2018. The Commission further observed
that, while much of this growth was in
states located in RTOs/ISOs, there also
was significant growth of non-utility
renewable generation in other states. For
example, net generation by non-utility
renewable resources in the region
defined by EIA as the Mountain State
region 376 increased from 3.6 TWh in
2005 to 19.5 TWh in 2012, and to 42.5
TWh in 2018. Pacific Northwest (Oregon
and Washington) net non-utility
generation from renewable resources
increased from 1.5 TWh in 2005, to 8.7
TWh in 2012, and to 10.6 TWh in
2018.377
241. The Commission found that EIA
data on independently-owned natural
gas-fired generation capacity told a
similar story. Natural gas-fired capacity
without the requisite cogeneration
technology cannot qualify as qualifying
small power production or
cogeneration, and thus most of this
capacity would not be within the scope
of the PURPA avoided cost rate
provisions. The Commission cited to
EIA data showing that, in 2018,
374 Id.
P 73.
P 74 (citing EIA, Today in Energy, North
Carolina has More PURPA-Qualifying Solar
Facilities than any other State, figure titled PURPA
qualifying facilities (1980–2015) percent of total
renewable capacity (Aug. 23, 2016), https://eia.gov/
todayinenergy/detail.php?id=27632).
376 Arizona, Colorado, Idaho, Montana, Nevada,
New Mexico, Utah, and Wyoming.
377 NOPR, 168 FERC ¶ 61,184 at P 74.
375 Id.
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
approximately 44% of all energy
produced by natural gas-fired generation
in the United States was generated by
independently-owned capacity.378 The
total amount of energy produced in
2018 by independently-owned natural
gas-fired generation was 651 TWh, an
increase of 13.7% from 2017.379 Again,
the percentage of independently-owned
natural gas generation outside of RTOs/
ISOs was lower than in RTOs/ISOs, but
still was significant. In the Mountain
State region, 21.4% of the energy
produced by natural gas-fired generation
in 2018 was produced by
independently-owned capacity, and in
Oregon and Washington 45.4% of
natural gas-fired energy was produced
by independently-owned capacity.380
From this, the Commission concluded
that independent owners of non-QF
generation have been, and continue to
be, able to obtain financing for their
facilities.381
242. The Commission did not suggest
that this evidence supports the
conclusion that substantial non-QF
capacity is being financed and
constructed without any form of fixed
revenue to support financing. Rather,
the Commission concluded that the
evidence demonstrated that the existing
PURPA avoided cost rate provisions are
not necessary for some independent
power generators to put in place
contractual arrangements, including
fixed revenue streams, that are sufficient
to obtain financing. The Commission
reasoned that QFs, which have the
ability to take advantage of PURPA’s
mandatory purchase requirements,
should be better positioned than nonQFs to negotiate the necessary
contractual arrangements for financing.
Moreover, the Commission noted that
QFs are equally as well positioned as
non-QF independent generators to take
advantage of federal and state incentives
designed to encourage the construction
of renewable resources. 382
243. Further, the Commission pointed
to evidence that the desire to limit the
effect of fixed QF contract rates had
directly led to PURPA implementation
issues that affected QF financing in
other respects, particularly with respect
to the length of QF contracts.383 For
example, a commissioner of the Idaho
378 NOPR, 168 FERC ¶ 61,184 at P 75 (citing EIA,
Electric Power Monthly with Data for December
2018, at tbl. 1.7.B, https://www.eia.gov/electricity/
monthly/current_month/epm.pdf.).
379 Id.
380 Id.
381 Id.
382 Id. P 76.
383 Id. P 65 (citing Natural Resources Defense
Council Comments, Docket No. AD16–16–000, at 4
(filed June 30, 2016)).
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
Commission testified at the Technical
Conference that the Idaho Commission’s
decision to limit QF contracts to a twoyear term was based on the Idaho
Commission’s concern that longer
contract terms at fixed rates would lead
to payments above avoided costs.384
Similarly, Southern Company testified
that the fixed rate requirement is
‘‘resulting in . . . typically shorter
contract term lengths.’’ 385 Golden
Spread Electric Cooperative
recommended that, if the fixed rate
requirement is not eliminated, the
Commission permit shorter contract
terms, ‘‘as short as one-year or three
years at most.’’ 386
244. Finally, the Commission
addressed one particular standard form
of QF contract rate currently employed
by a number of utilities, which is a onepart rate, applicable to each MWh of
energy delivered by the QF. This onepart rate is calculated to reflect both
avoided capacity costs and avoided
energy costs. Contracts employing such
rates also typically impose a must
purchase obligation on the purchasing
utility. The Commission stated that its
proposed rule was not intended to
prevent states from implementing such
an approach to setting QF contract rates
in the future. The Commission proposed
that, to the extent a state determines to
establish a one-part QF contract rate that
recovers both avoided capacity and
avoided energy costs, the rate must
continue to be subject to the QF’s option
to select a fixed rate for the term of the
contract, as provided in 18 CFR
304(d)(2)(ii). Any requirement to impose
a variable energy QF contract rate would
need to be accomplished through a
multi-part rate that includes separate
avoided capacity cost rates and avoided
energy cost rates.387
c. General Comments on the NOPR
Proposal
i. Comments in Support of NOPR
Proposal
245. Several commenters support the
NOPR proposal to allow energy rates to
384 Id. P 65 (citing Technical Conference Tr. at
142–43 (Idaho Commission) (‘‘No matter the
starting point, allowing QFs to fix their avoided cost
rates for long terms results in rates which will
eventually exceed and overestimate avoided cost
rates into the future. The longer the term, the
greater the disparity. . . . [The Idaho Commission]
recently reduced PURPA contract lengths to two
years in order to correct the disparity. We didn’t
reduce contract lengths to kill PURPA. We did it
to allow periodic adjustment of avoided cost
rates.’’)).
385 Id. P 65 (citing Technical Conference Tr. at
202 (Southern Company)).
386 Id. P 65 (citing Golden Spread Electric
Cooperative Comments, Docket No. AD16–16–000,
at 10 (filed June 30, 2016)).
387 Id. P 81.
PO 00000
Frm 00035
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
54671
vary in QF contracts and other LEOs,
arguing it will reduce overpayments and
protect customers.388 In that regard,
Duke Energy asserts that the primary
factor behind overpayment has been the
requirement to offer fixed avoided cost
energy rates during a period of rapidly
declining energy prices.389 Several other
commenters similarly cite to the general
decline of energy prices coupled with
the fact that QFs have been able to lock
in rates over the life of a contract or
other LEO as reasons for their support
of the NOPR proposal.390
246. Several commenters also support
the NOPR’s variable rate proposal
because it will allow states greater
flexibility to determine avoided cost
rates accurately and to meet PURPA’s
consumer protection goals.391 LG&E/KU
states that such flexibility is appropriate
and necessary to meet the statutory
requirement that ratepayers not pay a
rate that exceeds the electric utility’s
incremental cost of alternative
energy.392 NorthWestern argues that
providing such flexibility will assist in
guaranteeing that customers are held
harmless by purchases of QF power.393
247. Supporters of the NOPR variable
rate proposal also commented on
specific aspects of the proposal. These
comments are discussed in more detail
in the following sections.
ii. Comments in Opposition to NOPR
Proposal
248. Several commenters oppose the
NOPR variable energy rate proposal.394
388 Conservative Action Comments at 1;
Consumer Energy Alliance Comments at 2; EEI
Comments at 30–31; Idaho Power Comments at 7–
8; Idaho Commission Comments at 4; LG&E/KU
Comments at 3; NextEra Comments at 5; see also
Alaska Power Comments at 1; Arizona Public
Service Comments at 3–4; Basin Comments at 6–8;
Chamber of Commerce Comments at 4; Freedom
Center Comments at 1–2; R Street Comments at 5;
Tax Reform Comments at 1–2.
389 Duke Energy Comments at 5–7.
390 Consumer Energy Alliance Comments at 2;
Idaho Power Comments at 7–8; Idaho Commission
Comments at 4; LG&E/KU Comments at 3; Ohio
Commission Energy Advocate Comments at 4.
391 Alliant Energy Comments at 9; Duke Energy
Comments at 8–9; LG&E/KU Comments at 4; MA
DPU Comments at 1, 7; NorthWestern Comments at
6–7.
392 LG&E/KU Comments at 4.
393 NorthWestern Comments at 6–7.
394 Allco Comments at 9–11; AllEarth Comments
at 2; Biogas Comments at 2; BluEarth Comments at
2; CARE Comments at 3–5; Biological Diversity
Comments at 8; ELCON Comments at 18, 21–23;
EPSA Comments at 6–13; Massachusetts AG
Comments at 8–9; North Carolina DOJ Comments at
2–6; North Carolina Commission Staff Comments at
2–4; New England Hydro Comments at 8; NIPPC,
CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 29–48; North
American-Central Comments at 4–6; Public Interest
Organizations Comments at 6–7, 27–51; Resources
for the Future Comments at 4–7; Solar Energy
Industries Comments at 28–38; SC Solar Alliance
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
Continued
02SER2
54672
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
In addition to objections as to specific
aspects of that proposal, which are
discussed in the following sections,
some commenters raise threshold issues
regarding this proposal.
249. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA
cite to the PURPA Conference Report as
expressing Congress’s intent that QFs be
entitled to long-term fixed energy rates.
Specifically, they cite to the statement
in the Conference Report that ‘‘the
Commission and States should look to
the reliability of that power to the utility
and the cost savings to the utility which
may result at some later date by reason
of supply to the utility at that time of
power from the cogenerator or small
power producer.’’ 395 According to
NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA, this
statement shows that ‘‘Congress also
recognized that attempts to set the rates
based on the avoided costs at the time
of delivery would likely be insufficient
to encourage such facilities.’’ 396
250. Harvard Electricity Law asserts
that the Commission may not authorize
state regulators to change rates in
existing contracts.397 Harvard Electricity
Law then asserts that the Commission:
(1) Attempts to portray its agenda as
consistent with Congressional intent by
providing a skewed summary of the
legislative history; (2) presents an
unsupported statement that its rules
will ‘‘continue to encourage’’ QF
development, which ignores the
administrative record and fails to
account for regulatory changes since
PURPA’s enactment; (3) misreads its
own rules in claiming that repeal is
necessary to protect consumers; and (4)
relies on a finding that fixed price
energy contracts are not necessary to
encourage QFs that is based on
irrelevant data and questionable
assumptions that are not grounded in
reasoned decision making.
251. Harvard Electricity Law also
asserts that allowing long-term contracts
to include variable rates is contrary to
PURPA.398 In support of this assertion,
Harvard Electricity Law cites to two
decisions which it claims stand for the
proposition that the Commission’s
proposed rule would impose forbidden
utility-type regulation on QFs.399
Comments at 4–10; Southeast Public Interest
Organizations Comments at 9–18; sPower
Comments at 10–13; State Entities Comments at 2–
3; Mr. Mattson Comments at 26–27; Two Dot Wind
Comments at 11–13; Western Resource Councils
Comments at 2.
395 NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at
27 (quoting Conf. Rep. at 98–99).
396 Id.
397 Harvard Electricity Law Comments at 23
(citing API, 461 U.S. at 414).
398 Id. at 28.
399 Id. at 29 (citing Freehold Cogeneration Assoc.
v. Bd. of Regulatory Comm’rs. of N.J., 44 F.3d 1178,
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
252. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA
and Public Interest Organizations assert
that it is unclear whether independent
power producers that have obtained
financing did so with short-term
variable rate conditions.400 North
American-Central argues that, if a
variable rate will preclude a QF from
receiving financing in the first place, it
is irrelevant that a state might be more
willing to offer a longer-term
contract.401
iii. Commission Determination
253. In this final rule, we adopt
without modification the NOPR variable
rate proposal. We find that setting QF
energy avoided cost contract and other
LEO rates at the level of the purchasing
utility’s avoided energy costs at the time
the energy is delivered is consistent
with PURPA, which limits QF rates to
the purchasing utility’s avoided costs.
Indeed, a variable energy avoided cost
approach is a more accurate way to
ensure that payments to QFs equal, but
do not exceed, avoided costs.402 It is
inevitable that, in contrast, over the life
of a QF contract or other LEO a fixed
energy avoided cost rate, such as that
used in past years, will deviate from
actual avoided costs.
254. As described in more detail in
the following sections, the record
overwhelmingly supports our
conclusions that long-term forecasts of
avoided energy costs are inherently less
accurate, and that states should be given
the flexibility to rely on a more accurate
variable avoided cost energy rate
approach. Further, there are numerous
instances where overestimates and
underestimates have not balanced
out.403 When that has occurred,
1193 (3d Cir. 1995) (Freehold Cogeneration); Smith
Cogeneration Mgt. v. Corp. Comm’n., 863 P.2d 1227
(Okla. 1993) (Smith Cogeneration)).
400 NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at
46.
401 North American-Central Comments at 5–6.
402 16 U.S.C. 824a–3(b)(1).
403 See Duke Comments at 6 (Duke’s QF contracts
cost $4.66 billion but its ‘‘actual current avoided
costs’’ are $2.4 billion); Idaho Power Comments at
10–11 (‘‘The cost of PURPA generation contained in
Idaho Power’s base rates, on a dollars per MWh
basis, is not just greater than Mid-C market prices,
it is greater than all the net power supply cost
components currently recovered in base rates. Idaho
Power’s average cost of PURPA generation included
in base rates is $62.49/MWh. At $62.49/MWh, the
average cost of PURPA purchases is greater than the
average cost of FERC Account 501, Coal at $22.79/
MWh; greater than FERC Account 547, Natural Gas
at $33.57/MWh; greater than FERC Account 555,
Non-PURPA Purchases at $50.64/MWh; and
significantly greater than what is being sold back to
the market as FERC Account 447, Surplus Sales at
$22.41/MWh.’’); Portland General Comments at 5
(‘‘for a typical 3 MW Solar QF project that incurred
a LEO in 2016 and reaches commercial operations
three years later, [Portland General’s] customers
would pay 67% more for the project’s energy than
PO 00000
Frm 00036
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
consumers have borne the brunt of the
overpayments, which subsidized QFs,
in contravention of Congressional intent
and the Commission’s expectations.
255. Given that PURPA section 210(b)
prohibits the Commission from
requiring QF rates in excess of avoided
costs,404 this record evidence supports
our decision to give the states the
flexibility to require variable avoided
cost energy rates in QF contracts and
other LEOs to prevent QF rates from
exceeding avoided costs. We discuss
specific aspects of the variable energy
rate provisions below, but at the outset
address certain threshold issues raised
in the comments.
256. We reiterate the points made in
detail above in Section II. The variable
energy avoided cost rate provision is not
based on any determination that the
Commission’s rules no longer should
encourage QF development. The
question of whether QFs should
continue to be encouraged is a question
for Congress. Rather, we are revising the
PURPA Regulations by giving states the
flexibility to require variable avoided
cost energy rates in QF contracts and
other LEOs in order to better comply
if the 2019 avoided cost rate had been used. As a
result of this lag, [Portland General’s] customers
would pay an additional $1.6 million more for the
energy from the QF facility over the 15-year
contract term.’’); see also NOPR, 168 FERC 61,184
at P 64 n.101 (citing Alliant Energy, Comments,
Docket No. AD16–16–000, at 5 (filed Nov. 7, 2016)
(‘‘Current market-based wind prices in the Iowa
region of MISO are approximately 25% lower than
the PURPA contract obligation prices [Interstate
Power and Light Company] is forced to pay for the
same wind power for long-term contracts entered
into as of June 2016. As a result, PURPA-mandated
wind power purchases associated with just one
project could cost Alliant Energy’s Iowa customers
an incremental $17.54 million above market wind
prices over the next 10 years.’’) (emphasis in
original); EEI Supplemental, Comments, attach. A at
3–4 (‘‘On August 1, 2014, a 10-year fixed price
contract at the Mid-Columbia wholesale power
market trading hub was priced at $45.87/MWh. On
June 30, 2016, the same contract was priced as
$30.22/MWh, a decline of 34% in less than two
years. However, over the next 10 years, PacifiCorp
has a legal obligation to purchase 51.9 million
MWhs under its PURPA contract obligations at an
average price of $59.87/MWh. The average forward
price curve for the Mid-Columbia trading hub
during the same period is $30.22/MWh, or 50%
below the average PURPA contract price that
PacifiCorp will pay. The additional price required
under long-term fixed contracts will cost
PacifiCorp’s customers $1.5 billion above current
forward market prices over the next 10 years.’’);
Comm’r Kristine Raper, Idaho Commission
Comments, Docket No. AD16–16–000, at 3–4 (filed
June 30, 2016) (‘‘Idaho Power demonstrated that the
average cost for PURPA power since 2001 has
exceed the Mid-Columbia (Mid-C) Index Price and
is projected to continue to exceed the Mid-C price
through 2032. Likewise, PacifiCorp’s levelized
avoided cost rates for 15-year contract terms in
Wyoming shows a decrease of approximately 50%
from 2011 through 2015 (from approximately $60
per megawatt-hour to less than $30 per megawatthour).’’).
404 This prohibition is described in Section IV.A.
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
with Congress’s clear instruction in
PURPA that the Commission may not
require QF rates in excess of a
purchasing utility’s avoided costs.
257. By its very nature, the question
of fixed versus variable energy rates is
a question of how risk from increases in
avoided energy costs over the life of a
QF contract or other LEO should be
allocated. Answering this question
requires the Commission to allocate this
risk either to (i) customers of electric
utilities, or (ii) QFs and their investors
and lenders. But the Commission does
not have unlimited discretion in how it
resolves the question. Congress in
PURPA section 210(b) provided
guidance to the Commission in how it
should perform that allocation—by
mandating that the Commission cannot
adopt a rule that provides for a rate that
exceeds the incremental cost of
alternative electric energy.405
258. Opponents of variable avoided
cost energy rates urge the Commission
to continue placing this risk on the
customers of electric utilities, as it did
in the past, by retaining the option for
QFs to fix their avoided cost energy
rates in their contracts or LEOs
notwithstanding record evidence,
discussed elsewhere in this final rule,
that fixed energy rates compared to
actual avoided costs have not balanced
out over time. But, after consideration of
the record, the Commission has decided
instead to allow states to reduce the risk
to customers by giving states the
flexibility to require variable avoided
cost energy rates in QF contracts and
LEOs. The Commission’s determination
ensures that the PURPA Regulations
continue to be consistent with the
statutory avoided cost rate cap in
PURPA section 210(b), coupled with the
directive in the Conference Report that
customers of utilities not be required to
subsidize QFs.406
259. Third, there is no merit to the
contention that the PURPA Conference
Report expresses Congressional intent
that QFs are entitled to long-term fixed
energy rates. The statement in the
Conference Report cited by NIPPC,
CREA, REC, and OSEIA does not
support this contention.407 The example
provided in the PURPA Conference
Report was of a utility owning a
hydroelectric generating facility.
Congress hypothesized that this utility
might be able to avoid drawing down its
405 16 U.S.C. 824a–3(b); see also 16 U.S.C. 824a–
3(d); 18 CFR 292.101(b)(6), 292.304(b)(2).
406 Conf. Rep. at 98 (‘‘The provisions of this
section are not intended to require the rate payers
of a utility to subsidize cogenerators or small power
produc[er]s.’’) (emphasis added).
407 See NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments
at 27 (quoting Conf. Rep. at 98–99).
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
reservoir as a result of a purchase from
a QF, and thereby be able to generate
electricity from the hydroelectric facility
at a later date rather than running a
more expensive fossil fuel unit at that
later date. Congress stated that the
avoided cost in its example should be
based on the cost of the more expensive
fossil unit whose operation was avoided
at a later date rather than the avoided
cost at the time the QF delivered its
energy.408
260. While Congress recognized that
the better measure of avoided cost in
that scenario might be the cost of the
alternative fossil fuel unit that would
not be run at that later date,409 nothing
in the quoted section of the PURPA
Conference Report suggests that
Congress intended the Commission to
require that all avoided cost energy rates
be fixed at the outset for the life of a QF
contract or other LEO. And nothing in
the revision being implemented in this
final rule would prohibit a state from
calculating a QF’s avoided cost energy
rate for a QF contract or LEO in the
manner suggested in the PURPA
Conference Report or, indeed, in the
manner the Commission has long
allowed, if a state determined that such
an approach best reflects the purchasing
electric utility’s avoided costs.
261. Fourth, the variable avoided cost
energy rate provision adopted herein
does not run afoul of the Freehold
Cogeneration and Smith Cogeneration
cases cited by Harvard Electricity
408 Id. at 98–99 (‘‘In interpreting the term
‘incremental cost of alternative energy,’ the
conferees expect that the Commission and the states
may look beyond the cost of alternative sources
which are instantaneously available to the utility.
Rather, the Commission and states should look to
the reliability of that power to the utility and the
cost savings to the utility which may result at some
later date by reason of supply to the utility at that
time of power from the cogenerator or small power
producer; for example an electric utility which
owns a source of hydroelectric power and which is
offered the sale of electric energy from a cogenerator
or small power producer might, if measured over
the short term, have a low incremental cost of
alternative power because of its access to
hydropower; however, it may be the case that by
purchasing from the cogenerator or small power
producer and saving hydropower for later use, the
utility can avoided the use of expensive electric
energy generated by fossil fired units during later
months of its seasonal generation cycle. Thus,
viewed over the longer period of time, the
incremental cost of alternative electric energy might
be substantially higher than that measured by the
instantaneously available hydropower.’’).
409 Under the approach adopted in this final rule,
with the flexibility granted to states to adopt—but
not a mandate directing states to adopt—variable
avoided cost energy rates for QF contracts and other
LEOs, states can adopt a pricing approach that best
fits their circumstances, including adopting the
pricing approach described by the Conference
Report to address the circumstances described by
the Conference Report.
PO 00000
Frm 00037
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
54673
Law.410 Those decisions, which
overturned state avoided cost
determinations allowing for changes in
QF rates, were based on the provision in
the original PURPA Regulations giving
QFs the option to select contracts with
long-term fixed avoided cost rates.411
Indeed, the Smith Cogeneration
decision quotes at length from the
explanation in Order No. 69 of the
Commission’s justification for its
requiring in its regulations fixed
avoided cost rates in QF contracts and
LEOs.412 Neither decision suggests that
PURPA would prevent the Commission
from revising its regulations to allow
states the flexibility to require variable
avoided cost energy rates, as the
Commission is doing here.
262. Harvard Electricity Law also
relies on Freehold Cogeneration and
Smith Cogeneration to assert that the
Commission is imposing ‘‘utility-type’’
regulation in violation of Congressional
intent as expressed in the PURPA
Conference Report.413 However, those
holdings do not address the changes the
Commission is implementing here. By
adopting a provision that allows states
the option to require variable avoided
cost energy rates, we are not mandating
‘‘utility-type’’ regulation. The PURPA
Conference Report states that: ‘‘It is not
the intention of the conferees that [QFs]
become subject . . . to the type of
examination that is traditionally given
to electric utility rate applications to
determine what is the just and
reasonable rate that they should receive
for their electric power.’’ 414 Our action
today is consistent with that statement;
we are not subjecting QFs to the same
type of examination that is traditionally
given to electric utility rate applications
(e.g., cost-of-service rate regulation).
263. Indeed, the regulation adopted
today does not subject QF rates to any
examination whatsoever of the costs
incurred by QFs in producing and
selling power. Rather, the variable
avoided cost energy rate provision
applicable to QF contracts and other
LEOs that is adopted in this final rule
sets QF rates based on the avoided costs
410 Harvard Electricity Law Comments at 29
(citing Freehold Cogeneration, 44 F.3d at 1193;
Smith Cogeneration, 863 P.2d at 1227).
411 See Smith Cogeneration, 863 P.2d at 1241
(holding that allowing reconsideration of
established avoided costs ‘‘makes it impossible to
comply with PURPA and FERC regulations
requiring established rate certainty for the duration
of long term contracts for qualifying facilities that
have incurred an obligation to deliver power’’)
(emphasis added); Freehold Cogeneration, 44 F.3d
at 1193 (relying on Smith Cogeneration analysis
that ‘‘that PURPA and FERC regulations preempted
the State Commission rule’’) (emphasis added).
412 Smith Cogeneration, 863 P.2d at 1240.
413 Harvard Electricity Law Comments at 30.
414 Conf. Rep. at 97.
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
54674
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
of the purchasing utility. In no sense
can this variable avoided cost energy
rate provision be characterized as
imposing utility-style regulation on the
QFs themselves.
264. Finally, we agree with Harvard
Electricity Law that state regulators may
not change rates in existing QF contracts
or other existing LEOs.415 By its terms,
the variable energy avoided cost
provision adopted in this final rule
applies only prospectively to new
contracts and new LEOs entered into
after the effective date of this final rule.
Nothing in the final rule, including in
this preamble, should be read as
sanctioning the modification of existing
fixed-rate QF contracts and LEOs.
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
d. Whether the Current Approach Has
Resulted in Payments to QFs in Excess
of Avoided Costs
i. Comments in Support of NOPR
Proposal
265. Duke Energy states that its
experience shows the Commission’s
original assumption that
overestimations and underestimations
will balance out over time was
incorrect. From 2012 to 2017, Duke
Energy states that it experienced
explosive growth in solar QF contracts,
and entered into at a time of rapidly
declining natural gas prices—which
drove down Duke Energy’s avoided
costs. Duke Energy states that, as of July
1, 2019, it has almost 4,000 MW of QF
power under contract and in
commercial operation. Duke Energy
claims the total estimated financial
obligation on Duke Energy’s retail and
wholesale customers to pay for this QF
power is approximately $4.66 billion
over the next approximately 15 years. If
the contracts had been permitted to
contain rates that mirrored the utilities’
declining incremental costs either to
generate that electric energy itself or to
purchase alternative electric energy, i.e.,
Duke Energy’s ‘‘actual current avoided
costs,’’ Duke Energy asserts that the
contracts would be valued at $2.4
billion. Duke Energy claims that, among
the factors contributing to this
overpayment of $2.26 billion for the
remainder of these QF contracts, the
primary factor has been the requirement
to offer fixed avoided cost energy rates
during a period of rapidly declining
energy prices.416
266. EEI argues that relying on certain
avoided cost methods, such as the costs
of a proxy unit at a fixed point in time,
may result, and has resulted, in the over
estimation of future energy prices,
415 Harvard Electricity Law Comments at 23
(citing API, 461 U.S. at 414).
416 Duke Energy Comments at 6.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
leaving customers saddled with
uneconomic PURPA contracts.
According to EEI, the Commission’s
variable rate proposal will help ensure
that the variable energy rate more
accurately reflects the electric utility’s
actual avoided cost of energy so that
rates for customers are just and
reasonable. EEI describes this change as
important for states, especially those in
RTO/ISO markets, that elect to have the
avoided cost rate set at LMP.
267. EEI also submitted with its
comments a study performed by
Concentric Energy Advisors showing
that the avoided cost rates in the sample
of solar and wind QF contracts they
reviewed generally exceeded rates that
are realized in competitive markets for
solar and wind energy. According to
that report, the total overpayment
ranged between $2.7 billion and $3.9
billion. Several other commenters also
cited the Concentric Energy Advisors
report for the proposition that
consumers nationwide have overpaid
for QF contracts between 2009–2018.417
Berkshire Hathaway represents that
PURPA contracts held by PacifiCorp
will cost customers more than $1.2
billion above projected market costs
over the next 10 years.418
268. Massachusetts DPU argues that a
10-year, fixed energy rate based on
current New England wholesale energy
market prices is highly likely to diverge
from actual energy market prices over
the ten-year contract term and could
significantly harm ratepayers.419 Mr.
Transeth represents that Consumers
Energy’s QF contracts are priced
between 30 to 50% higher than their
current market value.420
269. APPA supports the variable
energy rate proposal because the
discrepancy between administratively
set, locked-in, long-run avoided costs
and actual market prices for the
purchase of equivalent energy can be
enormous, as demonstrated by the
evidence submitted in the Technical
Conference. According to APPA, were
continued development of the IPP and
renewable industries in jeopardy, the
Commission might have grounds to
conclude that enabling QFs to lock in
energy payments over the course of their
agreement is needed in order to bolster
these resources, but the growth in the
417 Alliant Energy Comments at 7–8; Conservative
Action Comments at 1; Duke Energy Comments at
5–7; Mr. Moore Comments at 2; Mr. Transeth
Comments at 2.
418 Berkshire Hathaway Comments at 5.
419 Massachusetts DPU Comments at 7 (citing
NOPR, 168 FERC ¶ 61,184 at 40).
420 Mr. Transeth Comments at 2.
PO 00000
Frm 00038
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
IPP and renewables industries in RTOs/
ISOs indicate otherwise.421
270. Commissioner O’Donnell asserts
that the Montana Public Service
Commission has addressed concerns
about overpayments by shortening QF
contract length from 25 years to 15,
which has resulted in litigation
currently pending before the Montana
Supreme Court. Commissioner
O’Donnell asserts that, because the
energy component of an avoided cost
rate reflects the price at which the
purchasing electric utility could
purchase power on the open market,
there is no need to fix that fluid energy
component for as long as 25 years.422
271. Competitive Enterprise asserts
that long-term fixed price rates ‘‘serve
only to reward certain financial
investors at the expense of consumers,
who are forced to pay inflated rates for
electricity’’ and insists that utilities
should only be required to purchase
from resources that are needed and
competitively priced.423
ii. Comments in Opposition to NOPR
Proposal
272. Harvard Electricity Law observes
that the Commission’s examples of
contract rates that exceed avoided costs
calculated years prior illustrate the
general proposition that ‘‘energy
forecasts have a manifest record of
failure.’’ 424 Harvard Electricity Law
notes, however, that in issuing Order
No. 69, the Commission recognized that
industry changes are difficult to
forecast, but the Commission
nonetheless concluded in Order No. 69
that the possibility that consumers
would be harmed by high rates was
outweighed by the Commission’s duty
to encourage QFs.425 Harvard Electricity
Law further claims that the repeal of the
fixed-price rule is not necessary to
protect consumers from rates in future
contracts.426 Harvard Electricity Law
argues that the Commission’s rules do
not require an annual matching between
avoided costs and rates, nor prevent
states from setting declining avoided
costs (which Order No. 69 explicitly
condones).427
273. Several commenters argue that
the NOPR’s assertion of artificially high
avoided cost rates is unsupported or
421 APPA
Comments at 16.
O’Donnell Comments at 2.
423 Competitive Enterprise Comments at 2.
424 Harvard Electricity Law Comments at 24
(citing Vaclav Smil, Energy at the Crossroads:
Global Perspectives and Uncertainties, Mass. Inst.
Tech., 2003, at 121, 145–149).
425 Harvard Electricity Law Comments at 24.
426 Id. at 23.
427 Id. at 23–24 (citing Order No. 69, FERC Stats.
& Regs. ¶ 30,128 at 30,881).
422 Commissioner
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
relies on flawed data and analysis.428
For example, NIPPC, CREA, REC, and
OSEIA argue that the Commission relied
on flawed data and analysis by using
actual market prices that resulted after
substantial QF penetration (which they
assert has reduced power prices).429
274. Public Interest Organizations
claim that the NOPR’s evidence of
overestimations is based on a selective
choice of years reflecting general
wholesale price declines, in which QF
contracts were executed just before
unforeseen natural gas price declines.430
Public Interest Organizations argue that
these recent electricity price
overestimations are not unique to QFs
and can be explained by general
declines in natural gas prices since the
adoption of hydraulic fracturing and the
2007–2009 recession.431
275. Public Interest Organizations
dispute Alliant’s asserted
overestimation by claiming that Alliant
likely would have procured non-QF
energy at the same price and further
point out that Alliant does not disclose
the data upon which it relies.432 Public
Interest Organizations assert that the
Commission similarly erred in relying
on EEI’s description of overestimations
of avoided costs in PacifiCorp’s QF
contracts because PacifiCorp only
compares those prices to the Mid-C hub
and does ‘‘not contain an analysis of the
long-term balancing of its forecasted
avoided energy rates with actual
avoided energy costs.’’ 433 Public
Interest Organizations contend that this
comparison implies that PacifiCorp
would have relied entirely on the MidC hub for all of its needs but for the QF
contracts.434
276. SC Solar Alliance contests Duke
Energy’s estimate of $2.26 billion in
overpayments for QF power. According
to SC Solar Alliance, ‘‘an expert witness
for South Carolina’s Office of Regulatory
Staff, which represents the interests of
the using and consuming public in
proceedings before the South Carolina
Commission, recently testified that
Duke’s estimation of ‘overpayments’ to
QFs was not reliable and that he
428 NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at
30; Public Interest Organizations Comments at 39–
40; Public Interest Organizations Comments at 43;
Solar Energy Industries Comments at 34–36.
429 NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at
30–31.
430 Public Interest Organizations Comments at 39–
40.
431 Id. at 47–50.
432 Id. at 40–41.
433 Id. at 41 (citing NOPR, 168 FERC ¶ 61,184 at
P 64 n.101 (citing EEI Supplemental Comments,
Docket No. AD16–16–000, attach. A at 3–4 (June 25,
2018))).
434 Id.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
‘wouldn’t put a whole lot of weight in
[Duke’s estimate].’ ’’ 435
277. GridLab attacks the conclusions
of the Concentric Report, raising two
principal arguments. First, according to
GridLab, QF contracts are executed in
non-competitive markets where utilities
do not perform competitive
solicitations. If QF avoided cost pricing
is higher than prices set through
competitive bidding, GridLab asserts
that is because the utility’s production
costs are higher than competitive
prices.436 Second, GridLab asserts that
Concentric has compared two datasets
that are different in several ways, most
notably project size—with larger
projects enjoying economies of scale
that result in lower costs. According to
GridLab, the difference in project size
and its impact on cost is a significant
factor that could account for the whole
of the reported increase on price.437
278. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA
argue that it was unreasonable for the
Commission in the NOPR to assume that
electricity price declines are permanent,
given recent integrated resource plans
(IRP) in the Northwest predicting
significantly increased electricity
demand and market prices at the MidC and Palo Verde hubs.438 NIPPC,
CREA, REC, and OSEIA represent that
electricity prices will climb significantly
in the Northwest. NIPPC, CREA, REC,
and OSEIA also assert that 100%
renewable or non-emitting generation
mandates and increased electrification
of transportation could substantially
increase electricity demand. NIPPC,
CREA, REC, and OSEIA contend that
fixed-price QF contracts protect
consumers from the potential for future
rising prices, market volatility, market
risk, and project risk.439
279. Resources for the Future reasons
that ‘‘while fixed prices determined
[five to ten] years ago would likely
exceed current average market prices,
that may not be true for fixed prices
determined either more recently or in
the future.’’ 440 Resources for the Future
states that, contrary to the NOPR, there
is no consensus that wind and solar
generation costs will continue to decline
because any capital cost declines will be
relatively modest and will be offset by
declining federal tax credits.441
Furthermore, Resources for the Future
attributes these cost declines to the
recent U.S. natural gas boom and points
out that this decline is therefore not
likely to continue.442 sPower similarly
argues that recent energy price declines
will not necessarily continue, especially
given expiring tax credits and additional
tariffs.443
280. Several commenters assert that
the risk of overpayments to QFs should
be compared to the alternative
generation sources used by the
utility.444 For example, ELCON claims
that critics who assert that QFs are
‘‘locking-in’’ consumers to artificially
high rates must acknowledge that utility
procurement does exactly the same via
the pre-approval process, sometimes for
even longer durations. ELCON argues
that QFs can only benefit consumers by
competing on a level playing field with
comparable terms and conditions.445
North Carolina Commission Staff
similarly asserts that the risk of
overpayment to QFs should be
considered in the context of a utility’s
long-term commitment to build plants
where ‘‘generation decisions are based
upon uncertain forecasts that could
result in ratepayers bearing the same
type of forecast risk from utility plants
as they do from QFs.’’ 446
281. According to Solar Energy
Industries, the risk from utility
generation construction is allocated to
ratepayers for the life of these assets
regardless of ongoing changes in energy
prices, while PURPA was designed to
shift this risk away from ratepayers.
Solar Energy Industries state that there
is no evidence that ratepayers are
harmed by long-term QF contracts any
more than other long-term contracts or
utility recovery of generation assets in
their rate base. Solar Energy Industries
state that, even though solar prices have
declined over time, solar QFs should
not be penalized for utility failures to
update their avoided cost calculations to
keep pace with such declines.447
282. The DC Commission states that,
with respect to the fact that long-term
contracts (e.g., 20 years) using fixed
avoided energy costs could create
stranded costs potentially due to
441 Id.
435 SC
Solar Alliance Comments at 7 (quoting
Public Service Commission of South Carolina,
Docket No. 2019–185 & 186–E, Hearing Transcript
Vol. 2 at 596, lines 6–21 (Horii Test.)) (attached as
Appendix 1 to SC Solar Alliance Comments).
436 GridLab Comments at 1–2.
437 Id. at 4.
438 NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at
33–34.
439 Id. at 34–36.
440 Resources for the Future Comments at 4.
PO 00000
Frm 00039
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
54675
at 5.
at 4.
443 sPower Comments at 10–11.
444 ELCON Comments at 22; North Carolina
Commission Staff Comments at 2–3; NIPPC, CREA,
REC, and OSEIA Comments at 31; Public Interest
Organizations Comments at 40, 43; Solar Energy
Industries Comments at 36–38.
445 ELCON Comments at 22.
446 North Carolina Commission Staff Comments at
2–3.
447 Solar Energy Industries Comments at 36–38.
442 Id.
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
54676
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
inaccurate projections, the chance of
creating stranded costs is substantially
reduced when the most up-to-date data
regarding avoided energy costs is used.
The DC Commission states that, if the
contract length is permitted to be
flexible, the possibility of stranded costs
would be significantly reduced for
shorter term contracts.448 The DC
Commission states that, without the
worry of stranded costs, there is no need
to eliminate the fixed price contract
option for QFs.449
iii. Commission Determination
283. As explained above, the NOPR
proposal to give states the flexibility to
require variable energy pricing in QF
contracts and other LEOs, instead of
providing QFs the right to elect fixed
energy prices, was based on the
Commission’s concern that, at least in
some circumstances, long-term fixed
avoided cost energy rates have been
well above the purchasing utility’s
avoided costs for energy—a result
prohibited by PURPA section 210(b).
And the record evidence demonstrates
just that, i.e., that QF contract and LEO
prices for energy can exceed and have
exceeded avoided costs for energy
without any subsequent balancing out.
In addition to the examples presented in
the record of the Technical Conference
that were cited in the NOPR,
commenters have provided additional
examples of such overpayments, as
described above.450 Such evidence has
persuaded us that it is necessary to give
states the flexibility to address QF
contract and LEO rates for energy that
exceed avoided costs for energy, while
at the same time still allowing states the
flexibility to continue requiring longterm fixed avoided cost energy rates in
QF contracts and other LEOs when such
treatment is appropriate.
284. As Harvard Electricity Law
concedes, the examples of QF contract
rates that exceed avoided costs that are
in the record illustrate the general
proposition that ‘‘energy forecasts have
a manifest record of failure.’’ 451 It is this
‘‘manifest record of failure’’ including
evidence in the record that the failure
has been at the expense of consumers,
that drives us to make the change
adopted in the final rule.452
448 DC
Commission Comments at 8.
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
449 Id.
450 See Duke Comments at 6; Idaho Power
Comments at 10–11; Portland General Comments at
5; NOPR, 168 FERC ¶ 61,184 at P 64 n.101.
451 Harvard Electricity Law Comments at 24
(citing Vaclav Smil, Energy at the Crossroads:
Global Perspectives and Uncertainties, Mass. Inst.
Tech., 2003, at 121, 145–149).
452 See, e.g., supra P 254 & note 403.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
285. While some commenters
challenge the idea that avoided cost
energy rates in QF contracts and other
LEOs have exceeded actual avoided
costs, their arguments largely either
concede that overestimations have
occurred while arguing that such
overestimations impacted purchasing
electric utilities just as much as QFs, or
attempt to argue that such
overestimations were temporary or
unusual. For these reasons, they assert
that the Commission should not
conclude that historical overestimations
of avoided cost require a change to the
current PURPA Regulations requiring
states to allow QFs to fix their avoided
costs energy rates for the term of their
contracts. These arguments do not cause
us to reconsider our determination, for
the reasons explained below.
286. First, Harvard Electricity Law’s
citation to the Commission’s original
determination in Order No. 69 that it
was not necessary to provide for
variable avoided cost energy rates
carries little weight.453 The purpose of
the NOPR was to reconsider the
Commission’s determinations made in
Order No. 69 in light of changes in
circumstances and additional evidence
that was not available to the
Commission when it issued Order No.
69 in 1980. The record evidence cited
above demonstrates that, contrary to the
Commission’s finding in 1980,
overestimations and underestimations
of future avoided costs may not even
out.454 Consequently, the Commission’s
determination in 1980 does not
preclude the Commission from changing
the rule adopted at that time.
287. We agree with Public Interest
Organizations that the recent electricity
price overestimations were not unique
to QFs and can be explained by general
declines in natural gas prices since the
adoption of hydraulic fracturing and the
2007–2009 recession.455 But that is
precisely why the estimates of avoided
costs reflected in the QF contracts and
LEOs were incorrect and why the
resulting fixed avoided cost energy rates
reflected in such QF contracts and other
LEOs resulted in QF rates well above
utility avoided costs in violation of
PURPA section 210(b); the precipitous
decline in natural gas prices caused a
corresponding reduction in utilities’
energy costs, and thus in their energy
avoided costs but this decline was not
453 Id. at 23–24 (citing Order No. 69, FERC Stats.
& Regs. ¶ 30,128, at 30,881).
454 See Duke Comments at 6; Idaho Power
Comments at 10–11; Portland General Comments at
5; NOPR, 168 FERC ¶ 61,184 at 64 n.101.
455 Public Interest Organizations Comments at 47–
50.
PO 00000
Frm 00040
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
reflected in the QFs’ fixed contract rates
that remained at their previous levels.
288. Similarly, arguments from
commenters that electric utilities also
based resource acquisitions on incorrect
forecasts of natural gas prices 456 ignore
a key distinction between utility rates
and fixed QF rates. Electric utilities may
have relied on incorrect natural gas
price forecasts to justify the timing and
type of their resource acquisitions, as
commenters assert. But once an electric
utility resource decision was made,
their cost-based rate regimes typically
obligated the electric utility eventually
to pass through to customers any energy
cost savings realized as a result of
declining natural gas and other fuel
prices, as well as any energy cost
savings due to lower purchased power
rates resulting from the decline in
natural gas prices. By contrast, once QF
avoided cost energy rates were fixed
based on now-incorrect (and now-high)
natural gas price forecasts, those energy
rates remained fixed for the term of the
QFs’ contracts and LEOs. Therefore,
unlike fixed avoided cost energy rates in
QF contracts and LEOs, cost-based
electric utility energy rates declined as
the cost of natural gas and other fuels
and purchased power declined.
289. We also disagree with Public
Interest Organizations’ assertions that it
was improper to have used competitive
market hub prices to determine whether
fixed QF contract and LEO prices
resulted in overpayments as compared
to electric utilities’ actual avoided
costs.457 We recognize that the
competitive market hub prices used in
the comparisons may not have precisely
reflected the avoided energy costs of all
electric utilities located in the same
region as the competitive market hub.
However, as explained above in the
discussion of the use of Market Hub
Prices to determine avoided energy
costs, competitive market prices in
general should reflect the marginal
avoided energy costs of utilities with
access to such markets. Certainly, those
markets generally reflect the marginal
cost of energy in the region.458 The
456 ELCON Comments at 22; North Carolina
Commission Staff Comments at 2–3; NIPPC, CREA,
REC, and OSEIA Comments at 31; Public Interest
Organizations Comments at 40, 43; Solar Energy
Industries Comments at 36–38.
457 Public Interest Organizations Comments at 40–
41.
458 A review of recent Mid-C Hub daily spot
prices (from Intercontinental Exchange (ICE)
https://www.eia.gov/electricity/wholesale/,
indicates that they reflect the marginal cost of
energy in that area since they are usually the result
of a significant number of trades (averaging 54 per
day), counterparties (averaging 16 per day), and
trading volume (averaging 26,714 MWh/day), which
usually exceed those of the NP–15 trading hub, an
active Western trading hub in Northern California
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
magnitude of the differences between
the market hub prices and the QF
contract and LEO prices provides solid
evidence that the QF contract and LEO
prices used in the comparison were well
above actual avoided energy costs at the
time the energy was delivered by the
QFs, even if the exact magnitude is
unclear.
290. We acknowledge that energy
prices may increase in the future, as
several commenters point out.459
However, as noted by Harvard
Electricity Law, ‘‘energy forecasts have
a manifest record of failure.’’ 460
Moreover, the fact that energy prices
may increase in the future does not
eliminate the risk that fixed avoided
cost energy rates could still be above
actual avoided costs. That is, if the
actual increase in energy prices is still
lower than the forecasted increase that
would form the basis of the fixed
avoided cost energy rate, then the fixed
avoided cost energy rate will be above
actual avoided energy costs. Giving
states the flexibility to require variable
avoided cost energy rates in QF
contracts and in other LEOs will allow
states to better ensure that avoided cost
energy payments made to QFs will more
accurately reflect the purchasing
utility’s avoided costs regardless of
whether energy prices are increasing or
declining. We also note that, if energy
prices do in fact increase, variable
avoided cost energy pricing would
protect and even benefit the QF itself, as
it would not be locked into a fixed
energy rate contract or LEO that would
be below the purchasing electric
utility’s avoided energy cost.
291. Although many commenters
agreed that fixed QF energy rates were
higher than actual avoided energy costs
in at least some instances, challenges
were raised against both Duke Energy’s
estimate that its fixed QF contract rates
were $2.6 billion above market costs,
and the Concentric Report’s comparison
of QF fixed rates for wind and solar
facilities with the cost of wind and solar
projects with competitive, non-PURPA
contracts.
in the CAISO footprint (averaging 6 trades per day,
4 counterparties per day, and 2,756/MWh per day).
The prices for Mid-C ranged between an average of
approximately $16/MWh high price and $13/MWh
low price during the recent spring (Mar 19–Jun 20,
2020). During this period the index was reported for
65 trading days for Mid-C and 9 trading days for
NP–15.
459 NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at
33–36; Resources for the Future Comments at 4;
sPower comments at 10–11.
460 Harvard Electricity Law Comments at 24
(citing Vaclav Smil, Energy at the Crossroads:
Global Perspectives and Uncertainties, Mass. Inst.
Tech., 2003, at 121, 145–149).
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
292. However, the expert testimony
cited by the SC Solar Alliance, that the
witness ‘‘wouldn’t put a whole lot of
weight in [Duke’s estimate],’’ 461 does
not address Duke’s calculation of past
overpayments. Rather, the witness was
answering a question regarding the
potential for overpayments ‘‘[f]or going
forward solar,’’ i.e., future overpayments
as a result of the new fixed avoided cost
rates being considered by the South
Carolina Commission that were the
subject of the expert witness’
testimony.462 The same witness
acknowledged the past overpayments
made by Duke Energy, which he
attributed to ‘‘drops in natural gas prices
that no one could’ve foreseen.’’ 463 It is
these overpayments due to unforeseen
declines in natural gas prices that form
an important basis for the Commission’s
determination in this final rule to now
give states the flexibility to require
variable avoided cost energy rates in QF
contracts and LEOs.
293. With respect to the criticisms of
the Concentric Report, we emphasize
that we have not relied on that report to
support the variable energy avoided cost
provision adopted in the final rule. It is
not clear that the lower cost of the
competitively priced renewable
resources identified in the report
represents the avoided costs of the
purchasing utilities that entered into the
QF contracts at fixed rates for renewable
resources under PURPA. Therefore, it is
not clear that the difference in costs
identified by Concentric can be ascribed
to the fixed rates in the QF contracts or
rather to the fact that the avoided cost
rates in the QF contracts were based on
more expensive non-renewable capacity
that was avoided by the purchasing
utilities.
e. Whether the Proposed Change Would
Violate the Statutory Requirement that
the PURPA Regulations Encourage QFs
i. Comments
294. Several commenters argue that
the NOPR’s variable rate proposal is
inconsistent with PURPA’s mandate
that the PURPA Regulations
‘‘encourage’’ the development of QFs.464
Southeast Public Interest Organizations
461 SC Solar Alliance Comments at 7 (quoting,
Public Service Commission of South Carolina,
Docket No. 2019–185 & 186–E, Hearing Transcript
Vol. 2, Tr. at 596: 6–21 (Horii Test)) (attached as
Appendix 1 to SC Solar Alliance Comments).
462 Public Service Commission of South Carolina,
Docket No. 2019–185 & 186–E, Hearing Transcript
Vol. 2, Tr. 596: 3–4 (Horii Test)) (attached as
Appendix 1 to SC Solar Alliance Comments).
463 Id. at 593:21–22.
464 Allco Comments at 9; Con Edison at 3, 4;
Harvard Electricity Law Comments at 1; North
American-Central Comments at 4–6; Southeast
Public Interest Organizations at 9–11.
PO 00000
Frm 00041
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
54677
state that removing QFs’ right to a fixed
energy rate would flout Congressional
intent that PURPA encourage QF
development because fixed rates are
necessary to attract QF financing.465
Harvard Electricity Law states that
Congress’s mandate to encourage QFs is
not contingent on industry conditions
and does not expire.466
ii. Commission Determination
295. As explained above in Section
IV.A.1, the statutory requirement that
the Commission’s PURPA Regulations
encourage QFs remains, but it is
bounded by the statutory provision in
PURPA section 210(b) that QF rates may
not exceed a purchasing utility’s
avoided costs. Further, as explained
above, we have determined, based on
the record evidence, that it is not
necessarily the case that overestimations
and underestimations of avoided energy
costs will balance out. Consequently, a
fixed energy rate in a QF contract or
LEO potentially could violate the
statutory avoided cost cap on QF rates.
296. The Commission’s PURPA
Regulations continue to encourage the
development of QFs by, among other
things, allowing a state to vary the rate
paid to the QF over time but in a way
that satisfies the rate cap established in
PURPA section 210(b). In this way, the
QF can obtain a higher rate when the
utility’s avoided costs increase, and
ratepayers are not paying more than the
utility’s avoided costs when prices
decrease. Furthermore, as discussed
above, allowing the use of variable
energy rates may promote longer
contract terms, which would help
encourage and support QFs.467 It
therefore is consistent with PURPA
section 210(b), as well as the obligation
imposed by PURPA section 210(a) to
revise the Commission’s PURPA
Regulations ‘‘from time to time,’’ to
provide the states the flexibility to
require that QF contracts and other
LEOs implement variable avoided cost
energy rates in order to prevent
payments to QFs in excess of the
purchasing electric utility’s avoided
energy costs. PURPA section 210(b)
prohibits the Commission from
requiring QF rates above avoided costs
even if, according to some commenters,
a fixed avoided cost energy rate would
provide greater encouragement to QFs
than a variable avoided cost energy rate.
465 Southeast Public Interest Organizations
Comments at 9–10.
466 Harvard Electricity Law Comments at 1.
467 See infra P 349.
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
54678
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
f. Discrimination
i. Comments in Support of NOPR
Proposal
297. Alliant Energy observes that
utility-owned generation and traditional
power purchase agreements (PPAs) are
subject to a demonstration of need and
that traditional PPAs are subject to reevaluation during their term to
determine whether they continue to be
cost-competitive and in the best
interests of customers. Alliant Energy
asserts that, by contrast, QFs are not
required to demonstrate that their
projects are needed and that, once a
contract is executed, it is not subject to
re-evaluation.468
ii. Comments in Opposition to NOPR
Proposal
298. Several commenters assert that
the NOPR’s variable avoided cost energy
rate proposal is discriminatory.469 For
example, EPSA argues that PURPA
requires the Commission to implement
regulations that, for rates for electric
utility purchases from QFs, ‘‘shall not
discriminate against qualifying
cogenerators or qualifying small power
producers.’’ EPSA describes this
standard as more restrictive than the
FPA’s prohibition against ‘‘unduly
discriminatory’’ rates. According to
EPSA, the fact that long-term QF
contracts are substantially above
prevailing market prices due to
declining wholesale prices over the
long-term does not justify the variable
rate proposal because electric utilityowned generation is similarly based on
imperfect long-term forecasts of energy
prices that oftentimes prove to be too
high. EPSA therefore argues that the
NOPR variable rate proposal should not
be adopted unless utility-owned assets
are also subject to a similar cost
recovery regime.470
299. sPower describes the NOPR
proposal to allow variable rates as
providing a significant advantage to
electric utilities over QFs, given that
electric utilities themselves, according
to sPower, have not had to lower rates
to consumers as energy prices have
declined.471 ELCON asserts that pushing
more market risk to QFs while utility
assets remain insulated from markets
creates an investment risk asymmetry.
ELCON claims this puts QFs at a
468 Alliant
Energy Comments at 6–7.
Comments at 21–22; SC Solar Alliance
Comments at 5–10; sPower Comments at 13; see
also ELCON Comments at 22; North Carolina
Commission Staff Comments at 2–3; NIPPC, CREA,
REC, and OSEIA Comments at 31; Public Interest
Organizations Comments at 40, 43; Solar Energy
Industries Comments at 36–38.
470 EPSA Comments at 8–9.
471 sPower Comments at 13.
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
469 ELCON
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
competitive disadvantage and shifts the
consumer burden to more utility builds,
which have generally been higher cost
than merchant builds.472
300. SC Solar Alliance states that
utilities often rely on fuel price forecasts
over time to justify rate base approval
for generation assets that might run
beyond price forecasts. SC Solar
Alliance argues that allowing utilities
this right, but not QFs, holds QFs to a
much higher standard than utilities and
therefore is discriminatory.473
301. Commissioner Slaughter argues
that, by removing the fixed, long-term
contract option for independent power
producers, the NOPR threatens to
hamper the competitiveness of
renewable-based energy firms
challenging vertically integrated utilities
in many localities across the country.474
iii. Commission Determination
302. The discrimination claims are
based on the incorrect assumption that
electric utilities have not been required
to lower their energy rates as prices
have declined. To the contrary, as
explained above, utilities typically
charge their customers cost-based rates,
and as their fuel and purchased power
costs have declined, they typically have
been required to provide corresponding
reductions in the energy portion of their
rates to their customers.475 Requiring
QF avoided cost energy rates to likewise
change as purchasing electric utilities’
avoided energy costs change does not
create a discriminatory difference, but
rather puts QF rates on par with utility
rates.
303. Further, we are not changing the
requirement that QF avoided cost
energy rates be set at the purchasing
utility’s full avoided energy costs. As
the Supreme Court held in API, ‘‘the
full-avoided-cost rule plainly satisfies
the nondiscrimination requirement.’’ 476
Rather, we are allowing the states the
option to now choose to require QF
avoided cost energy rates that vary with
the purchasing utility’s avoided costs of
energy, rather than QF avoided cost
rates that are fixed for the life of the
QF’s contract or LEO, to ensure the rates
comply with PURPA.
g. Effect of Variable Energy Rates on
Financing
i. Comments in Support of the NOPR
Proposal
304. Several commenters state that
fixed energy payments are not necessary
472 ELCON
Comments at 21–22.
Solar Alliance Comments at 5–10.
474 Commissioner Slaughter Comments at 4.
475 See supra PP 40, 122, 288.
476 API, 461 U.S. at 413.
473 SC
PO 00000
Frm 00042
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
for QFs to obtain financing.477 Alliant
states that it is on track to be the third
largest utility owner-operator of wind
facilities in the United States, with 1.9
GW on its system and in addition is
increasing the pace of solar resource
development in its Wisconsin territory.
Alliant states it therefore does not
believe that the proposed change will
slow renewable deployment and
adoption.478
305. Several commenters assert that
PURPA’s must-purchase requirement
itself should necessarily afford QF
developers a degree of certainty and
enables developers to attract capital at
advantageous terms.479 The Idaho
Commission states that, even if
modified as proposed, QF contract
terms would remain superior to
competitively bid renewable projects
where the energy is not ‘‘must take’’ and
curtailment and other reliability
parameters are imposed.480
306. Finadvice and APPA argue that
maintaining a fixed capacity rate, as
proposed by the Commission, will help
attract capital and ameliorate any
negative effect that the variable energy
rate proposal may impose.481 Ohio
Commission Energy Advocate argues, as
evidence that QFs can still flourish
under a variable energy rate, that the
PJM market has successfully attracted
new supplies and ensured resource
adequacy through fixed capacity and
variable energy rates.482
307. The Idaho Commission states
that variable energy prices protect the
ratepayer while allowing the QF to
ensure a stream of revenue through a
longer-term contract. The Idaho
Commission affirms that the rapid
growth of non-QF renewable projects
and their ability to obtain financing
should quell any concerns about a QF’s
ability to obtain financing as long as
PURPA’s ‘‘must take’’ provision
remains.483 Commissioner O’Donnell
asserts that QFs should bear some
market risk as energy prices rise and fall
in a way that balances risks to all
parties.484
308. EEI argues that PURPA does not
require the Commission or the states to
implement regulations that guarantee a
477 APPA Comments at 16–17; Indiana
Commission Comments at 6.
478 Alliant Energy Comments at 6.
479 APPA Comments at 16–17; Finadvice
Comments at 2; Idaho Commission Comments at 4;
Commissioner O’Donnell Comments at 3.
480 Idaho Commission Comments at 4.
481 APPA Comments at 16–17; Finadvice
Comments at 2.
482 Ohio Commission Energy Advocate Comments
at 3–4.
483 Idaho Commission Comments at 4.
484 Commissioner O’Donnell Comments at 3.
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
QF’s financeability. EEI represents that
Congress intended QFs to be treated
similarly to merchant generation and
simply required QFs to have nondiscriminatory access. According to EEI,
because QFs are not subjected to the
oversight or regulatory responsibilities
applicable to electric utilities, it was not
expected or intended that QFs be treated
the same as electric utilities.485
Similarly, Duke argues that the central
design criteria for PURPA rates and
terms should be customer indifference,
just and reasonableness, and nondiscrimination. Duke Energy states that
a design that requires QF financeability
as a criterion will inevitably lead to a
QF boom and customer harm.486 Duke
Energy further asserts that several
factors affect financeability and that,
therefore, claims by QFs that they
require fixed energy payments for
financing purposes should be
rejected.487
309. EEI claims QFs that require thirdparty financing will still be able to
obtain financing if the Commission
adopts the proposals in the NOPR,
because they are additional options, in
addition to those currently being used
by states, that will be available to
determine avoided costs. EEI maintains
that a QF developer will be able to
obtain financing under any of the
options, provided it can build a costefficient plant that can profit at an
avoided cost rate.488 EEI claims that
independent power producers lacking
the certainty of the mandatory purchase
obligation are building most renewable
generation today because merchant
power plants may be developed and
financed using a variety of hedging and
risk management tools, such as
commodity hedges, that lock in cash
flows and facilitate construction at the
outset.489
310. APPA states that much of the
renewable development that has
occurred over the past 20 years has
taken place within RTO/ISO footprints
and therefore is largely unaided by
PURPA obligations.490
311. Duke Energy states that concern
about the potential for fixed avoided
cost contract rates exceeding actual
avoided costs at the time of delivery
have led both North Carolina and South
Carolina to enact laws placing limits on
the length of QF contracts.491 The Idaho
Commission states that there is no
485 EEI
Comments at 35.
Energy Comments at 17–18.
487 Id. at 13.
488 EEI Comments at 35–36.
489 Id. at 36.
490 APPA Comments at 16–17.
491 Duke Energy Comments at 9; LG&E/KU
Comments at 4.
486 Duke
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
evidence that variable energy prices
would be fatal to QF development.492
The Idaho Commission states that it
reduced contract length on large
projects to two years because it did not
interpret the Commission’s current rules
to allow for a variable energy rate inside
a long-term contract. The Idaho
Commission states that, because its
experience dictated that the longer the
contract term, the more inflated the
avoided cost rate, the Idaho Commission
set parameters to balance QF interests
against utility ratepayer interests. The
Idaho Commission states that an energy
rate established at the time of contract
formation that provides for ‘‘revisions to
the energy rate at regular intervals,
consistent with, for example, a
purchasing electric utility’s [integrated
resource planning (IRP)] to reflect
updated avoided cost calculations’’
would allow states to consider longer
term contracts without putting
ratepayers at risk.493 NorthWestern
represents that the Montana
Commission has lowered the length of
QF contracts from 25 to 15 years in
response to the current requirement that
QFs are entitled to fixed avoided cost
rates for energy in their contracts and a
concern that rates calculated at the time
a contract is signed are likely to change
over the life of that contract.494
ii. Comments in Opposition to the
NOPR Proposal
312. Many commenters assert that the
NOPR’s variable energy rate proposal
will result in QFs being unable to obtain
financing.495 Several commenters also
assert that it is discriminatory that
utilities and non-QF generators can ratebase long-term investments and recover
actual operating costs, while the NOPR’s
proposed rules would deprive QFs of a
reasonable ability to forecast their cost
recovery with no guarantees.496
492 Idaho
493 Id.
Commission Comments at 4.
(citing NOPR, 168 FERC ¶ 61,184 at P 5
n.5).
494 NorthWestern
Comments at 6–7.
495 Allco Comments at 9; AllEarth Comments at
2; Biogas Comments at 2; BluEarth Comments at 2;
Biological Diversity Comments at 8; Commissioner
Slaughter Comments at 4; Con Edison Comments at
3, 4; Covanta Comments at 7–8; DC Commission
Comments at 6–8; Distributed Sun Comments at 1;
EPSA Comments at 2; Energy Recovery at 4;
Harvard Electricity Law Comments at 5;
Massachusetts AG Comments at 8–9; New England
Hydro Comments at 8; NIPPC, CREA, REC, and
OSEIA Comments at 37–38; North Carolina DOJ
Comments at 3, 6; North American-Central
Comments at 4–6; Public Interest Organizations
Comments at 6–7; Resources for the Future
Comments at 6–7. SC Solar Alliance Comments at
5–7; Southeast Public Interest Organizations
Comments at 9–11; State Entities Comments at 2–
3; Two Dot Wind Comments at 11–13.
496 Allco Comments at 9; Commissioner Slaughter
at 4; Harvard Electricity Law Comments at 5;
PO 00000
Frm 00043
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
54679
313. Several commenters assert that
the NOPR lacks evidence on the record
to conclude that the variable rate
proposal would not affect the ability of
QFs to obtain financing.497 NIPPC,
CREA, REC, and OSEIA argue that the
NOPR contained no record evidence
demonstrating how this proposal would
continue to encourage QFs in a nondiscriminatory manner,498 and lacks
evidence on how QF generation can be
financed without a fixed energy rate.499
Similarly, Harvard Electricity Law
asserts that repealing the fixed-price
PPA requirement is premised on
irrelevant data and ignores the record,
and disagrees with the Commission’s
demonstration of information on nonQF capacity to show that QF
development no longer relies on
contracts with fixed energy rates.500
314. Public Interest Organizations
assert that testimony from Southern
Company, American Forest and Paper
Association, and Solar Energy
Industries, upon which the NOPR relies,
states that non-QF renewable PPAs
generally entail fixed energy rates rather
than variable energy rates.501 In
particular, Public Interest Organizations
state that testimony from Solar Energy
Industries, refers to reliance on fixed
rates for energy and/or capacity without
describing them as alternatives but
rather ‘‘an acknowledgement that a
[power purchase agreement] may
provide fixed capacity in addition to
fixed energy revenue, not a suggestion
that a QF can be developed without a
predictable energy revenue stream.’’ 502
315. Allco describes programs in
California, Massachusetts, Connecticut,
and Vermont that offer standard QF
contract programs with variable energy
rates, none of which, according to Allco,
have led to the construction of solar
projects.503 Allco claims that these
programs prove that, without the ability
to obtain a fixed long-term forecasted
rate, QF solar energy development will
NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 36–
37; Public Interest Organizations Comments at 6–7;
Solar Energy Industries at 29–30.
497 NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at
29, 46; Harvard Electricity Law Comments at 22,
25–27; Public Interest Organizations Comments at
6–7, 33–35.
498 NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at
29.
499 Id. at 46–48.
500 Harvard Electricity Law Comments at 22, 25
(citing NOPR, 168 FERC ¶ 61,184 at PP 69–70, 76).
501 Public Interest Organizations Comments at 33–
35 (citing NOPR, 168 FERC ¶ 61,184, at P 70 n.114
(citing Tech. Conference, Docket No. AD16–16–000,
Tr. at 153, 200 (filed June 30, 2016))).
502 Id. at 35 (citing NOPR, 168 FERC ¶ 61,184, at
P 70 n.115 (citing Solar Energy Industries
Comments, Docket No. AD16–16–000, at 3 (filed
June 30, 2016))).
503 Allco Comments at 10.
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
54680
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
not exist.504 Southeast Public Interest
Organizations assert that Southeastern
states with fixed QF energy rates have
seen vigorous QF development, while
Southeastern states with variable energy
rates have seen virtually no QF
development, undermining the
Commission’s assertion that QFs can be
financed without fixed energy rates.505
316. Covanta and Energy Recovery
state that the NOPR’s variable rate
proposal would have an especially
negative effect on Waste to Energy
facilities.506 Covanta states that, because
Waste to Energy depends on finite local
tax resources, a loss in energy revenue
due to price variability cannot be easily
replaced.507 Covanta states that, without
adequate QF pricing and multi-year
contracts (and consistent, predictable
pricing throughout the life of the
contract), local governments may be
forced to close their Waste to Energy
facilities prematurely, to minimize loss
and stranding that investment.508
Energy Recovery states that the inability
to secure suitable rates through a longterm contract has closed seventeen
Waste to Energy facilities in the last
fifteen years.509
317. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA
state that the NOPR’s anecdotal reliance
on tax incentives to encourage QF
development is irrelevant because these
incentives are declining or
disappearing, thereby requiring QFs to
rely even more on energy rates.510
NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA predict
that the NOPR’s proposed rules would
make QF development riskier and
would thereby slow the development of
new technologies such as energy
storage, hydrogen fuels, and other
advanced renewable energy
technologies.511
318. Solar Energy Industries states
that financing for QFs differs from
financing for fossil fuel generators
because ‘‘much of the cost of
installation is incurred up-front, but
once installed, the generation has little,
if any, variable cost.’’ 512 Likewise,
Harvard Electricity Law observes that
wind and solar QFs, for example, have
higher capital costs, lower operating
costs, and provide energy intermittently,
and therefore have characteristics that
at 9–11.
Public Interest Organizations
Comments at 9–11, 15–16.
506 Covanta Comments at 7–8; Energy Recovery
Comments at 1, 4.
507 Covanta Comments at 7–8.
508 Id. at 8.
509 Energy Recovery Comments at 3.
510 NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at
40–41.
511 Id. at 41–42.
512 Solar Energy Industries Comments at 30.
may present different financing
challenges as compared to non-QF
natural gas fired capacity.513 Similarly,
Public Interest Organizations argue that,
unlike independent power producer
natural gas generators with fixed
capacity payments and variable energy
costs, renewable QFs rely on fixed
energy payments to cover their capital
costs given their own nominal variable
energy costs.514
319. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA
state that the financeability of
generation with fixed capacity prices
and variable energy prices inside RTOs/
ISOs is irrelevant to regions that lie
outside of RTOs/ISOs.515 NIPPC, CREA,
REC, and OSEIA criticize the NOPR’s
reliance on an independent power
producer natural gas turbine’s
financeability outside the RTO/ISO
context as irrelevant to QFs because
these natural gas turbines receive fixed
capacity payments and variable energy
payments to account for the fluctuating
price of fuel; whereas a QF would need
a sufficient fixed capacity payment to
support financing and an energy rate
that removes market risk.516
320. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA
state that the NOPR’s reference to
hedging instruments to reduce risks
from fluctuating prices is irrelevant.517
NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA state
that hedging makes projects less
financeable because it increases
transaction and compliance costs for
small power producer QFs that cannot
afford large legal divisions and trading
floors to employ such hedges.518
321. Resources for the Future states
that wind projects have used bank
hedges, synthetic PPAs, and proxy
revenue swaps.519 Resources for the
Future claims, however, that these
products would be inaccessible to most
wind QFs if fixed energy payments are
eliminated. Resources for the Future
argues that solar QFs would have even
less access to such hedging given their
smaller size and high transaction costs.
Resources for the Future states that QFs
under 5 MW in RTO/ISOs and QFs
outside of RTO/ISOs thus would be
unable to obtain financing.520
322. Solar Energy Industries states
that QFs in RTO/ISO markets without a
fixed energy rate would require a
504 Id.
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
505 Southeast
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
513 Harvard
514 Public
Electricity Law Comments at 26.
Interest Organizations Comments at 33–
hedging instrument to finance their
projects. Solar Energy Industries further
states that QFs outside RTO/ISO
markets without a fixed energy rate
would be unable to finance their
projects because they would have no
access to such hedging mechanisms.521
Solar Energy Industries states that the
NOPR failed to consider which markets
offer financial products, whether these
financial products are available to QFs
outside RTOs/ISOs, and whether these
products will be sufficient to provide
financing to QFs.522
323. Solar Energy Industries states
that financing for QFs differs from
financing for fossil fuel generators
because much of the cost of installation
is incurred up-front, with virtually no
variable costs. Solar Energy Industries
states that, because of this difference,
financiers ‘‘examine the QF’s projected
revenue stream to ensure that the
revenue stream is sufficient to recover
the installed costs plus a competitive
return.’’ 523 Solar Energy Industries
reasons that QFs must therefore know in
advance their facility’s energy and
capacity values and obtain a legally
enforceable contract that fits into
common underwriting models.524
324. North Carolina DOJ asserts that
allowing avoided cost energy prices to
fluctuate could eliminate fixed-price
power sales contracts, thereby making
compensation to QFs more volatile and
discouraging renewable energy
financing.525
325. Distributed Sun agrees with
Commissioner Glick’s dissent on the
NOPR that revoking the fixed energy
price requirement would halt the
construction of most distributed energy
resources.526 Solar Energy Industries
states that it is not aware of a
meaningful number of QFs that have
been constructed using capacity rates
alone or capacity rates with variable
energy rates.527
326. Mr. Mattson argues that a
variable rate or a rate based on a
projected stream of revenues during the
contract are not long-term contracts. Mr.
Mattson argues that this violates
legislative intent and precedent and is
not viable, suggesting that PURPA
requires avoided cost data to be kept by
a utility for public inspection.528
327. Western Resource Councils
represents that PURPA, in the rural
34.
515 NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at
42–43.
516 Id.
517 Id. at 44–45 (citing NOPR, 168 FERC ¶ 61,184
at P 72 & n.117).
518 Id. at 45–46.
519 Resources for the Future Comments at 6.
520 Id. at 6–7.
PO 00000
Frm 00044
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
521 Solar
522 Id.
Energy Industries Comments at 30.
at 31.
523 Id.
524 Id.
525 North
Carolina DOJ Comments at 3.
Sun Comments at 3.
527 Solar Energy Industries Comments at 28.
528 Mr. Mattson Comments at 26.
526 Distributed
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
Northern Plains and Rocky Mountain
West, is the only vehicle for small
businesses to obtain project financing
and that variable rates undermine the
certainty of QFs obtaining financing.529
328. Public Interest Organizations
assert that the NOPR has no basis to
speculate that the Idaho Commission
shortened contract lengths to two years
because of the fixed rate requirement or
that it would provide longer contracts if
it could require variable energy rates.530
According to Public Interest
Organizations, the fact that no solar and
wind QFs have been developed since
the Idaho Commission set a two year
contract length, even while they are
currently entitled to fixed rates, shows
that allowing variable rates will further
discourage wind and solar QF
development.531
329. sPower argues that, even with
long-term contracts, QFs will not be
viable without fixed energy rates and
explains that, if the Commission seeks
to encourage states to offer longer
contract terms, it should just require
longer terms.532
330. The DC Commission states that,
in the jurisdictions where the contract
length has been adjusted to ‘‘shortterm,’’ such as Idaho’s two-year
contract,533 further elimination of the
QF fixed price contract option would
discourage or eliminate new small
renewable energy facilities entering the
markets, which is not consistent with
PURPA’s objective of encouraging the
construction of renewable generation.534
331. NIPPC, CREA, REC, OSEIA, and
Public Interest Organizations argue that
the fact that states have shortened the
length of QF contracts in response to
fixed energy prices means that the
Commission should require a minimum
contract length.535 Green Power
supports the creation of longer-term
standard contract lengths for both
cogeneration and small power
production facilities.536 Green Power
recommends that cogeneration
developers are offered 5, 8, or 10-year
contracts and that small power
producers developers are offered 10, 15,
or 20-year contracts.537 Mr. Mattson
proposes that long-term contracts,
529 Western
Resource Councils Comments at 2.
Interest Organizations Comments at 36.
531 Id. at 35–38.
532 sPower Comments at 11.
533 DC Commission Comments at 8 (citing NOPR,
168 FERC ¶ 61,184 at P 77).
534 Id.
535 NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at
47–48; Public Interest Organizations Comments at
6–7.
536 Green Power Comments at 2, 10.
537 Id. at 10.
defined as 20 years or longer, be
available to QFs at their discretion.538
332. CARE notes that a purchasing
utility’s fixed capacity value may be
zero if the state determines that the
electric utility has no need for
additional capacity resources. In that
circumstance, there would be no fixed
element in an avoided cost contract,
which CARE believes would be
inconsistent with the Commission’s
rationale justifying variable energy rate
contracts.539 EPSA similarly argues that,
as noted in the NOPR, an electric utility
is not required to pay for QF capacity
that the state has determined is not
needed. EPSA claims that the variable
rate proposal therefore would create
substantial uncertainty for QF
developers and investors in non-ISO/
RTO regions.540
333. American Biogas argues that
LMP prices are not sufficient to sustain
existing biogas projects or to increase
their number.541 Several commenters
state that LMP cannot sustain QFs in
general.542
334. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA
argue that the NOPR proposal to base
QF pricing on LMP or Western EIM will
limit competition, because QFs will be
stuck with no long-term assurance of
investment recovery, and thus with no
means to finance their projects, while
regulated incumbent utilities will be
able to rate-base their generation assets,
thus guaranteeing long-term recovery of
their investments.543 NIPPC, CREA,
REC, and OSEIA maintain that prices for
long-term QF contracts should be set by
reference to long-term price indices or
other indicators that, unlike highlyvariable LMP and Western EIM prices,
genuinely reflect the long-term costs of
generation avoided by the purchasing
utility.544
iii. Commission Determination
335. As an initial matter, the
Commission agrees with commenters
that PURPA does not guarantee QFs a
rate that guarantees financing. PURPA
only requires the Commission to adopt
rules that encourage the development of
QFs; it does not provide a guarantee that
any particular QF will be developed or
profitable. This is evident from the
structure of PURPA, which caps QF
rates at the purchasing utility’s avoided
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
530 Public
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
538 Mr.
Mattson Comments at 7–9.
Comments at 4 n.7.
540 EPSA Comments at 12.
541 Biogas Comments at 2.
542 BluEarth Renewables Comments at 2;
Biological Diversity at 8; Covanta Comments at 9;
Public Interest Organization Comments at 43–44.
543 NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at
55–56.
544 Id. at 53.
539 CARE
PO 00000
Frm 00045
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
54681
costs rather than providing for rates that
guarantee the recovery of a QF’s costs.
The legislative history confirms that
Congress did not intend to guarantee QF
financing. As stated in the PURPA
Conference Report, ‘‘the Conferees
recognize that [QFs] are different from
electric utilities, not being guaranteed a
rate of return on their activities
generally or on the activities vis-a-vis
the sale of power to the utility and
whose risk in proceeding forward in the
[QF] enterprise is not guaranteed to be
recoverable.’’ 545
336. Notwithstanding that PURPA
does not guarantee QF financeability,
the Commission believes that the
variable avoided cost energy rate option
implemented by this final rule will still
allow QFs to obtain financing.
337. Before addressing specific
comments on this issue, however, we
reiterate that we are not eliminating
fixed rate pricing for QFs. Under this
final rule, QFs will continue to be able
to require fixed avoided cost capacity
rates in their contracts and LEOs.
Capacity costs, as relevant here, include
the cost of constructing the capacity
being avoided by purchasing utilities as
a consequence of their purchases from
QFs. As will be discussed below, a
combination of fixed avoided cost
capacity rates and variable energy rates
can provide important revenue streams
that can support the financing of QFs.
338. Furthermore, merely because
QFs have had access to fixed avoided
cost energy rates does not mean that
QFs must have access to such rates to
obtain future financing. Up to now, QFs
have had the right under the PURPA
Regulations to both fixed capacity and
fixed energy rates, and we understand
that most QFs executing long-term
contracts have exercised this right.
Commenters insisting that the
Commission cannot allow states the
option to impose variable avoided cost
energy rates without evidence that QFs
have obtained financing under such
contract structures 546 are attempting to
impose a standard that could never be
satisfied.
339. In any event, there is ample
evidence outside of the PURPA context
demonstrating that generation projects
with fixed capacity rate-variable energy
contracts are financeable. As the
Commission explained in detail in the
NOPR, since the time of the passage of
PURPA a large new independent power
production industry has developed in
545 Conf.
Rep. at 97–98 (emphasis added).
Solar Energy Industries Comments at 28;
NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 29,
46; Harvard Electricity Law Comments at 22, 25–
27; Public Interest Organizations Comments at 6–7,
33–35.
546 See
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
54682
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
the United States. Like QFs,
independent power producers sell
power at wholesale, and have no ability
to rate-base their facilities or to
otherwise recover their costs through
regulated rates to retail customers,
unlike traditional utilities with
franchised service territories and retail
customers. Unlike QFs, however,
independent power producers have had
no right to require utilities to purchase
their power or to impose fixed energy
cost pricing in their power sales
contracts.547
340. The record shows that, even
without the right to require long-term
fixed energy rates, non-QF independent
power producers nevertheless have been
able to obtain financing for large
amounts of generation capacity,
including from renewables. EIA data
shows that, in 2019, approximately 44%
of all energy produced by natural gasfired generation in the United States
was generated by independently owned
capacity.548 Furthermore, EIA data
demonstrates that net generation of
energy by non-utility owned renewable
resources in the United States grew by
almost 700% between 2005 and 2018,
which speaks to the reality that
renewable resources are able to acquire
financing even without the right to
require long-term fixed energy rates.549
Based on this data, we find that the right
to require counterparties to pay fixed
energy rates is not essential for the
financing of independent power
generation capacity.
341. We acknowledge that a number
of different financing mechanisms were
used for this independent power
generation capacity, not all of which
will be available to QFs. Nevertheless,
we understand that a standard rate
structure employed in the electric
industry is a fixed capacity rate-variable
energy rate structure, and that many
independent power production facilities
have been financed based on this
structure.550 Accordingly, record
547 See
NOPR, 168 FERC ¶ 61,184 at P 76.
Electric Power Monthly with Data for
December 2018, at tbl. 1.7.B (February 2020),
https://www.eia.gov/electricity/monthly/archive/
february2020.pdf).
549 Id. P 74 (explaining that net generation of
energy by non-utility owned renewable resources in
the United States escalated from 51.7 TWh in 2005
when EPAct 2005 was passed, to 340 TWh in 2018)
(citing EIA, Electricity Data Browser, www.eia.gov/
electricity/data/browser).
550 American Public Power Association, How New
Generation is Funded (Aug. 29, 2018), https://
www.publicpower.org/blog/how-new-generationfunded (‘‘Beginning in 2015, merchant generation
[in RTOs/ISOs markets] began to increase
dramatically from prior years, amounting to 19.3
percent of new capacity in 2015, 7.2 percent in
2016, and 29.1 percent in 2017.’’). In RTOs and
ISOs with capacity markets, merchant generators
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
548 EIA,
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
evidence and historical data regarding
the financing and construction of
significant amounts of independent
power production facilities supports the
Commission’s conclusion that a fixed
capacity rate-variable energy rate
structure—which will apply in those
states choosing the variable avoided cost
energy rate option—also will support
financing of QFs.
342. For the reasons described below,
we do not find compelling the concerns
expressed by some commenters that a
fixed capacity rate-variable energy rate
construct may not work for solar and
wind resources, which have high fixed
capacity costs and minimal variable
energy costs.551 Similarly, we are not
persuaded by comments that point out
that energy rates in typical independent
power production contracts are
designed to recover the cost of a
facility’s fuel, whereas variable energy
rates would provide no such
guarantee.552
343. As an initial matter, as we have
noted, the record demonstrates that the
amount of renewable resources being
developed outside of PURPA greatly
exceeds the amount of renewable
resources developed as QFs.553
Renewable resources developed outside
of PURPA may not have a legal right to
long-term contracts with fixed energy
rates, yet nevertheless have been able to
obtain financing.
344. The Commission also disagrees
with those commenters who assert that,
as a consequence of the above factors,
the Commission should ‘‘require[] the
variable energy component to be
structured in a way that removes market
risk from the QF.’’ 554 This argument
runs directly counter to one of the
fundamental premises of PURPA, which
is that QFs must accept the market risk
associated with their projects by being
paid no more than the purchasing
utility’s avoided cost, thereby
preventing utility retail customers from
subsidizing QFs.555 PURPA does not
allow the Commission to require QFs to
are compensated through variable energy rates and
fixed capacity rates, along with whatever ancillary
service revenues they can earn.
551 See Harvard Electricity Law Comments at 26;
Public Interest Organizations Comments at 33–34;
Solar Energy Industries Comments at 30.
552 NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at
42–43.
553 See supra P 240.
554 NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at
43.
555 See Conf. Rep. at 97–98 (stating that the ‘‘risk
in proceeding forward in the [QF] enterprise is not
guaranteed to be recoverable’’); accord API, 461
U.S. at 416 (holding that QFs ‘‘would retain an
incentive to produce energy under the full-avoidedcost rule so long as their marginal costs did not
exceed the full avoided cost of the purchasing
utility’’).
PO 00000
Frm 00046
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
be paid rates above avoided costs in
order to make certain types of QF
technologies financeable. If a state
determines that it is necessary to require
variable avoided cost energy rates in
order to avoid paying QFs an aboveavoided cost rate, which is a bedrock
requirement of PURPA, then the impact
this may have on facilities not
financeable with a fixed capacity ratevariable energy rate contract structure is
a direct result of the requirements of
PURPA itself.556 Concerns regarding the
alleged mismatch between avoided costs
and the costs of renewable technologies
therefore are collateral attacks on the
requirements of PURPA itself, not our
proposed implementation of it.
345. In the NOPR, the Commission
noted the availability of various hedging
devices that would allow QFs to fix or
limit the variability of a variable
avoided cost energy rate.557 We
acknowledge those comments
explaining that hedging tools increase
project expense and may not be
available to all QFs.558 However, the
Commission never intended to suggest
that hedging is cost-free or that it would
be appropriate for all QFs. The
commenters all agree that hedging is
available for at least some QFs.559 For
such QFs, hedging can help provide
energy rate certainty if such certainty is
required for financing. To the extent
that certainty is required, then the cost
of hedging is a part of the cost of
financing the project that PURPA
requires QFs to bear.
346. Public Interest Organizations cite
testimony from the Technical
Conference stating that Southern
Company has negotiated non-QF
renewable contracts with fixed energy
rates rather than variable energy
rates.560 However, that testimony does
not support the contention that the
Commission must provide for fixed
avoided cost energy rates for QF
contracts and other LEOs. As the cited
testimony notes, Southern agreed to
contracts with longer terms and with
fixed energy rates only because the
556 See Connecticut Authority Comments at 14
(‘‘[C]ontracted QF rates that take into account New
England market conditions would not deter lenders
and investors. Many QFs have no fuel costs and low
variable costs of production; therefore, it is
reasonable to find that these QFs would earn
substantial inframarginal rents on energy sales.
Further, QFs may be able to sell RECs and/or
participate in other Connecticut programs.’’).
557 NOPR, 168 FERC ¶ 61,184 at P 72.
558 NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at
45–46; Resources for the Future Comments at 6–7;
Solar Energy Industries Comments at 30.
559 Id.
560 Public Interest Organizations Comments at 33–
34 (citing NOPR, 168 FERC ¶ 61,184 at P 70 n.114
(citing Tech. Conference, Docket No. AD16–16–000,
Tr. 200 (filed June 30))).
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
renewable energy developers agreed to a
rate that was 50 to 60 percent of the
projected long-term avoided cost.561
347. Certain commenters expressed
concern that, when a purchasing electric
utility is not avoiding the construction
or purchase of capacity as a
consequence of entering into a contract
with a QF, under the NOPR’s proposed
rules a state could limit the QF’s
contract rate to variable energy
payments.562 However, in that event,
the only costs being avoided by the
purchasing electric utility would be the
incremental costs of purchasing or
producing energy at the time the energy
is delivered.563 Nothing in PURPA or
the legislative history of PURPA
suggests that the Commission should set
QF rates so as to facilitate the financing
of new QF capacity in locations where
no new capacity is needed.
348. In the NOPR, the Commission
also observed that the variable avoided
cost energy rate proposal might cause
states to make other changes to their
administration of PURPA in ways that
would improve the financeability of QF
projects. Most notably, states that had
limited the length of contract terms
because of concerns about
overpayments for energy might be
willing to allow longer term contracts if
the contracts have variable avoided cost
energy rates. Longer term contracts with
fixed avoided cost capacity rates, in
turn, would provide greater revenue
assurance to QFs.564 The comments
561 Tech. Conference, Docket No. AD16–16–000,
Tr. at 200 (filed June 30). The Commission notes
that the PURPA Regulations specifically permit QFs
and utilities to agree to rates that differ from what
the PURPA Regulations require. 18 CFR 292.301(b).
As the testimony cited by the Public Interest
Organizations suggests, QFs that believe fixed
energy avoided cost rates are required to obtain
financing are free to offer rate and/or other
contractual concessions in exchange for a fixed rate.
562 CARE Comments at 4 n.7; EPSA Comments at
12.
563 See, e.g., City of Ketchikan, 94 FERC ¶ 61,293,
at 62,061 (2001) (‘‘[A]voided cost rates need not
include the cost for capacity in the event that the
utility’s demand (or need) for capacity is zero. That
is, when the demand for capacity is zero, the cost
for capacity may also be zero.’’).
564 NOPR, 168 FERC ¶ 61,184 at P 65. Contrary to
assertions by some commenters, the Commission’s
conclusion in the NOPR about the possible positive
effects of the variable avoided cost energy rate
proposal was not based on speculation. See Public
Interest Organizations Comments at 36. Rather, the
Commission relied on testimony presented at the
Technical Conference. See Technical Conference
Tr. at 142–43 (Idaho Commission) (‘‘No matter the
starting point, allowing QFs to fix their avoided cost
rates for long terms results in rates which will
eventually exceed and overestimate avoided cost
rates into the future. The longer the term, the
greater the disparity. . . . [The Idaho Commission]
recently reduced PURPA contract lengths to two
years in order to correct the disparity. We didn’t
reduce contract lengths to kill PURPA. We did it
to allow periodic adjustment of avoided cost
rates.’’).
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
submitted in response to the NOPR
support our analysis.
349. Further, there is some evidence
that variable avoided cost energy rates
in contracts and LEOs could result in
longer-term contracts.565 To be clear, we
are not finding that the variable avoided
cost energy rate provision in this final
rule will necessarily lead to longer term
contracts and LEOs in every state, nor
does our decision to adopt this
provision rely on such a finding.566
However, the record supports the
conclusion that the variable avoided
cost energy rate provision could lead to
longer term contracts in at least some
states, and that likelihood provides
support for the conclusion that QFs will
be able to obtain financing for their
projects under this provision if their
costs are indeed below the purchasing
utility’s avoided costs.
h. Other Claimed Benefits of Fixed
Avoided Cost Energy Rates
i. Comments
350. Public Interest Organizations
assert that maintaining the requirement
to pay QFs fixed rates serves as a hedge
for consumers because QFs, unlike
utilities, bear their own risks and have
provided ‘‘billions of dollars’’ in
benefits to consumers. Public Interest
Organizations assert that eliminating
QFs’ rights to fixed rate contracts
ignores these benefits to consumers and
puts them at risk.567 Likewise, Solar
Energy Industries portrays a fixed
energy rate as providing a hedge to a
utility that the purchasing electric
utility may use as a revenue stream in
connected markets. Solar Energy
Industries nevertheless argues that, in
order to encourage QF development, the
Commission must ensure that QFs know
565 Idaho Commission Comments at 4 (allowing
states to set variable QF energy avoided costs
‘‘would allow states to consider longer term
contracts without putting ratepayers at risk’’) (citing
NOPR, 168 FERC ¶ 61,184 at 5 n.5).
566 We are not finding that variable avoided cost
energy rates would be appropriate only if they
cause states to require longer term contracts, and we
are not adopting the suggestion made by certain
commenters that the Commission order states to
require longer contract terms. See NIPPC, CREA,
REC, and OSEIA Comments at 47–48; Public
Interest Organizations Comments at 6–7; sPower
Comments at 11.
567 Public Interest Organizations Comments at 45–
46 (citing S. Rep. No. 95–442, at 9, 22–23, 33 (1977),
as reprinted in 1978 U.S.C.C.A.N. 7903, 7906,
7919–21, 7930; Public Interest Organizations,
Comments, Docket No. AD16–16–000, at 5, 19–21
(Oct. 17, 2018)). In earlier comments in Docket No.
AD16–16–000, cited by Public Interest
Organizations in response to the NOPR, Public
Interest Organizations asserted that long-term fixed
QF contracts often act as a hedge that lowers QF
financing expenses, which benefits ratepayers, and
insulates ratepayers from fuel price fluctuations.
Public Interest Organizations, Comments, Docket
No. AD16–16–000, at 20–21 (Oct. 17, 2018).
PO 00000
Frm 00047
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
54683
the energy price at the time of
contracting and that utilities publish
rates stating the energy, capacity, and
environmental attributes of the QF
rate.568
ii. Commission Determination
351. Fixed and variable energy rates
each can provide benefits to electric
utility customers. These benefits are the
converse of each other: Variable avoided
cost energy rates provide protection to
customers when energy costs decline,
and fixed avoided cost energy rates
provide protection to customers when
energy costs increase. By giving the
states the flexibility to choose either
variable or fixed avoided cost energy
rates in QF contracts and LEOs, the
Commission is giving each state the
ability to choose the protection that is
best suited for electric customers in
their state, based on each state’s view of
what the future may hold and the
likelihood that variable energy avoided
costs will exceed fixed energy avoided
costs during the life of a QF contract or
LEO.
352. We acknowledge that fixed
avoided energy cost rates can serve as a
hedge against future fuel price increases
in a way that protects ratepayers,
assuming such price increases actually
occur. Given that PURPA both places an
avoided cost cap on QF rates, and
requires that such rates must be just and
reasonable to the electric consumers of
the electric utility, we find it is
appropriate to provide flexibility to
states to decide how to apportion such
risks to their ratepayers in a way that
ensures QF avoided energy cost rates are
consistent with PURPA’s requirements
(i.e., by using either fixed or variable
avoided cost energy rates to best meet
those requirements).
353. We caution, though, that having
made that choice, a state is not free to
toggle a QF’s contractual rate structure
back and forth unilaterally from one to
the other as circumstances change; QFs
are entitled to the certainty that once a
state has made its choice with respect to
a particular QF’s contract or LEO, that
QF’s contract or LEO is not subject to
change during the term of that contract
or LEO except by mutual consent.
i. Potential Modifications to NOPR
Proposal
i. Comments
354. The California Commission,
Connecticut Authority, and
Massachusetts DPU support the variable
energy rate proposal and suggest that, in
addition, states be given the discretion
568 Solar
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
Energy Industries Comments at 31–32.
02SER2
54684
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
to require the avoided capacity rate to
vary.569
355. In contrast, NIPPC, CREA, REC,
and OSEIA urge the Commission, if it
allows variable energy rates, to adopt
strict parameters for setting capacity
rates in order to provide some
predictability to QFs to allow them to
obtain financing. NIPPC, CREA, REC,
and OSEIA recommend that the
Commission require forecasted capacity
rates be ‘‘offered in a long-term contract
of at least 20 years after commencement
of sales under the agreement’’ for ‘‘[a]ll
years during the term of the QF’s longterm contract after which the utility
forecasted to be capacity deficit in its
load and resource balance, as forecasted
in its resource plan in effect at the time
of the legally enforceable obligation’’
and ‘‘[a]ny time the utility is planning
or undertaking actions to acquire a
major generation resource or a major
capital investment at an aging facility at
the time of creation of the legally
enforceable obligation.’’ 570
356. Commissioner O’Donnell urges
the Commission to provide additional
guidance to states on the minimum
required contract duration that would
enable a QF to obtain financing from
investors while providing sufficient
ratepayer protections.571
ii. Commission Determination
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
357. We decline to adopt the
California Commission’s, Connecticut
Authority’s, and Massachusetts DPU’s
requests to permit a state to require
variable avoided cost capacity rates in
addition to variable avoided cost energy
rates. There is a fundamental difference
between avoided energy costs and
avoided capacity costs. Unlike avoided
energy costs, which fluctuate with
changes in the variable cost of the
purchasing utility’s marginal energy
resource, a purchasing utility’s avoided
capacity cost is determined at the time
the utility incurs the obligation to
purchase capacity from a QF rather than
self-build a capacity resource or enter
into a power purchase agreement with
a third party. Although a purchasing
utility’s avoided capacity cost may later
change as additional capacity
acquisitions are avoided, the cost of the
capacity avoided by the purchasing
utility as a consequence of purchasing
capacity from a particular QF at a
particular moment in time does not
change.
569 California Commission Comments at 27–28;
Connecticut Authority Comments at 14–15;
Massachusetts DPU Comments at 8–10.
570 NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at
51.
571 Commissioner O’Donnell Comments at 3.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
358. As a simple illustrative example,
if a utility is able to avoid constructing
a new generation facility with a capacity
cost of $10/MW-month as a result of
purchasing power from a QF, its
avoided capacity cost is the $10/MWmonth capacity cost that it would have
been incurred to construct the new
facility. Once the utility commences its
purchases from the QF, it may not need
additional capacity, and its avoided
capacity cost for the next QF would
drop to $0/MW-month. It would not be
appropriate to then reduce the original
QF’s avoided capacity charge to $0/MWmonth, however, because the only
reason that the utility does not need
additional capacity is because it already
purchased capacity from the original QF
in order to avoid the $10/MW-month
capacity cost. That is, without the
purchase from the original QF, the
utility would have incurred a capacity
cost of $10/MW-month, and that is the
utility’s avoided capacity cost for the
term of its contract with the original QF.
It would be inappropriate, in other
words, for avoided cost capacity rates to
change after they are first set at the time
a LEO (such as a contract) is established.
359. We also decline to adopt the
suggestion of NIPPC, CREA, REC, and
OSEIA to adopt additional criteria for
establishing avoided capacity costs,
including minimum contract lengths.
We believe that the existing rate-setting
provisions adequately set out the
criteria that should be considered by a
state in determining avoided capacity
costs.572 To the extent that any party
believes a state has not appropriately
applied these criteria, that party has
recourse to the enforcement provisions
of PURPA sections 210(g) and (h).573
360. We decline to specify a
minimum required contract length given
that it is up to states to decide
appropriate contract lengths in a way
that accurately calculates avoided costs
so as to meet all statutory requirements.
8. Consideration of Competitive
Solicitations To Determine Avoided
Costs
a. NOPR Proposal
361. The Commission in the NOPR
proposed to revise the PURPA
Regulations in 18 CFR 292.304 to add
subsection (b)(8). In combination with
new subsection (e)(1), this subsection
would permit a state the flexibility to set
avoided cost energy and/or capacity
rates using competitive solicitations
572 See
18 CFR 292.304(e).
also Policy Statement Regarding the
Commission’s Enforcement Role Under Section 210
of the Public Utility Regulatory Policies Act of 1978,
23 FERC ¶ 61,304.
573 See
PO 00000
Frm 00048
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
(i.e., requests for proposals or RFPs),
conducted pursuant to appropriate
procedures.
362. The Commission recognized that
one way to enable the industry to move
toward more competitive QF pricing is
to allow states to establish QF avoided
cost rates through a competitive
solicitation process. The Commission
previously has explored this issue. In
1988, the Commission issued a notice of
proposed rulemaking proposing to
adopt regulations that would allow
bidding procedures to be used in
establishing rates for purchases from
QFs.574 That rulemaking proceeding,
along with several related proceedings,
ultimately was withdrawn as overtaken
by events in the industry.575
363. Since then, the Commission held
in a 2014 order addressing the specific
facts of the particular competitive
solicitation at issue that an electric
utility’s obligation to purchase power
from a QF under a LEO could not be
curtailed based on a failure of the QF to
win an only occasionally-held
competitive solicitation.576 In a separate
proceeding involving a different
competitive solicitation, the
Commission declined to initiate an
enforcement action where the state
competitive solicitation was an
alternative to a PURPA program.577
364. Given this precedent, the
Commission proposed to amend its
regulations to clarify that a state could
establish QF avoided cost rates through
an appropriate competitive solicitation
process. Consistent with its general
approach of giving states flexibility in
the manner in which they determine
574 Regulations Governing Bidding Programs,
FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 32,455 (1988) (crossreferenced at 42 FERC ¶ 61,323) (Bidding NOPR);
see also Administrative Determination of Full
Avoided Costs, Sales of Power to Qualifying
Facilities, and Interconnection Facilities, FERC
Stats. & Regs. ¶ 32,457 (1988) (cross-referenced at 42
FERC ¶ 61,324) (ADFAC NOPR).
575 See Regulations Governing Bidding Programs,
64 FERC ¶ 61,364 at 63,491–92 (1993) (terminating
Bidding NOPR proceeding); see also Administrative
Determination of Full Avoided Costs, Sales of Power
to Qualifying Facilities, and Interconnection
Facilities, 84 FERC ¶ 61,265 (1998) (terminating
ADFAC NOPR proceeding).
576 See, e.g., Hydrodynamics, Inc., 146 FERC
¶ 61,193, at PP 31–35 (2014) (Hydrodynamics).
Competitive solicitation processes have been
used more recently in a number of states, including
Georgia, North Carolina, and Colorado. Georgia’s
competitive solicitation process is described at Ga.
Comp. R. & Regs. 515–3–4.04(3) (2018). North
Carolina’s competitive solicitation process is
described at 4 N.C. Admin. Code 11.R8–71 (2018).
Colorado’s competitive solicitation process is
described at sPower Development Co., LLC v.
Colorado Pub. Utils. Comm’n, 2018 WL 1014142 (D.
Colo. Feb. 22, 2018).
577 Winding Creek Solar LLC, 151 FERC ¶ 61,103,
reconsideration denied, 153 FERC ¶ 61,027 (2015).
But see Winding Creek Solar LLC v. Peterman, 932
F.3d 861 (9th Cir. 2019).
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
avoided costs, the Commission did not
propose in the NOPR to prescribe
detailed criteria governing the use of
competitive solicitations as tools to
determine rates to be paid to QFs, as
well as to determine other contract
terms. The Commission stated that
states arguably may be in the best
position to consider their particular
local circumstances, including
questions of need, resulting economic
impacts, amounts to be purchased
through auctions, and related issues.
365. Nevertheless, in considering
what constitutes proper design and
administration of a competitive
solicitation, the Commission found it
was appropriate to establish certain
minimum criteria governing the process
by which competitive solicitations are
to be conducted in order for a
competitive solicitation to be used to set
QF rates. In that regard, the Commission
noted that it has addressed competitive
solicitations in prior orders in a number
of contexts that provide potential
guidance to states and others. For
example, the Commission’s policy for
the establishment of negotiated rates for
merchant transmission projects,578 the
Bidding NOPR, and the Hydrodynamics
case 579 all suggest factors that could be
considered in establishing an
appropriate competitive solicitation that
is conducted in a transparent and nondiscriminatory manner.
366. These factors, as proposed in the
NOPR, include, among others: (a) An
open and transparent process; (b)
solicitations should be open to all
sources to satisfy the purchasing electric
utility’s capacity needs, taking into
account the required operating
characteristics of the needed
capacity; 580 (c) solicitations conducted
at regular intervals; (d) oversight by an
independent administrator; and (e)
certification as fulfilling the above
578 Allocation of Capacity on New Merchant
Transmission Projects and New Cost-Based,
Participant-Funded Transmission Projects, 142
FERC ¶ 61,038 (2013).
579 See Hydrodynamics, 146 FERC ¶ 61,193 at P
32 n.70 (citing Bidding NOPR, FERC Stats. & Regs.
¶ 32,455 at 32,030–42). The Commission notes that,
while QFs not awarded a contract pursuant to an
competitive solicitation would retain their existing
PURPA right to sell energy as available to the
electric utility, if the state has concluded that such
QF capacity puts tendered after an competitive
solicitation was held are ‘‘not needed,’’ the capacity
rate may be zero because an electric utility is not
required to pay a capacity rate for such puts if they
are not needed. See Hydrodynamics, 146 FERC
¶ 61,193 at P 35 (referencing City of Ketchikan, 94
FERC ¶ 61,293 at 62,061 (‘‘[A]voided cost rates need
not include the cost for capacity in the event that
the utility’s demand (or need) for capacity is zero.
That is, when the demand for capacity is zero, the
cost for capacity may also be zero.’’)).
580 See 18 CFR 292.304(e); Windham Solar, 157
FERC ¶ 61,134 at PP 5–6.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
criteria by the state regulatory authority
or nonregulated electric utility. The
Commission proposed that a state may
use a competitive solicitation to set
avoided cost energy and capacity rates,
provided that such competitive
solicitation process is conducted
pursuant to procedures ensuring the
solicitation is transparent and nondiscriminatory. The Commission
proposed that such a competitive
solicitation must be conducted in a
process that includes, but is not limited
to, the factors identified above which
would be set forth in proposed
subsection (b)(8).
367. In addition, the Commission
sought comment on whether it should
provide further guidance on whether,
and under what circumstances, a
competitive solicitation can be used as
a utility’s exclusive vehicle for
acquiring QF capacity.581
b. Comments
i. Comments in Opposition
368. Several commenters oppose the
NOPR proposal to allow states the
ability to set avoided cost energy and
capacity rates through a competitive
solicitation such as an RFP.582
369. Allco states that allowing a state
commission to use a competitive
solicitation price is simply giving
another tool to a state commission to
eliminate QF projects.583 Allco also
contends that this proposal creates an
apples and oranges scenario where a
competitive solicitation could be won
by solar projects of 80 MWs at a low,
steeply discounted price that may never
get built, resulting in a state commission
publishing that as an avoided cost for a
1 MW solar project connected to the
distribution system.584 Allco points to
California’s Renewable Marketing
Adjustment Tariff program as an
example of a competitive solicitation
price failure.585
370. CA Cogeneration states that
relying on a competitive solicitation
violates PURPA’s mandatory purchase
obligation, and the regulations must
always preserve the right of a QF to
negotiate a contract for the purchase of
581 The Commission proposed that, even if a
competitive solicitation were used as an exclusive
vehicle for an electric utility to obtain QF capacity,
QFs that do not receive an award in the competitive
solicitation would be entitled to sell energy to the
electric utility at an as-available avoided cost
energy rate.
582 Allco Comments at 12; Blue Earth Comments
at 1–2; Boulder Comments at 6; CA Cogeneration
Comments at 10–11; Green Power Comments at 1–
3; Industrial Energy Consumers Comments at 13.
583 Allco Comments at 12.
584 Id.
585 Id.
PO 00000
Frm 00049
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
54685
its output at an avoided cost rate.586 CA
Cogeneration states that reliance on a
competitive solicitation also fails to
provide the necessary financial and
operational encouragement for
combined heat and power.587
371. Covanta asserts that the
Commission’s proposed competitive
solicitation process would disadvantage
technologies like Waste to Energy that
are not growing, or are closing
facilities.588
372. Southeast Public Interest
Organizations argue that, in the states
that currently require some form of
competitive solicitation, many utilities
do not regularly hold competitive
solicitations, do not make competitive
solicitations open to all QFs, or do not
provide QFs the ability to sell to the
utility outside of a competitive
solicitation process.589 Southeast Public
Interest Organizations maintain that the
competitive solicitation process can be
overly burdensome and costly for
smaller facilities. Southeast Public
Interest Organizations assert that no
state requires, and no utility conducts,
a competitive solicitation to determine
how best to meet the ongoing energy
needs that it currently meets through
the operation of its existing generation
fleet and market purchases.590 In
particular, Southeast Public Interest
Organizations represent that: (1) Florida
does not require an independent
evaluator as part of its competitive
solicitation process; (2) Colorado and
Oklahoma allow utilities to apply for
waivers of the competitive solicitation
requirement; and (3) North Carolina
allows the incumbent utility to
participate in the competitive bidding
process and to receive preferential
treatment in the form of waiving post
bid security required for any
independently owned projects.591
Southeast Public Interest Organizations
conclude that, while a well-designed
and well-implemented competitive
solicitation process could be an
appropriate procurement and ratesetting tool in some cases, competitive
solicitations should never be the only
way to set rates or for QFs to sell their
output, and close consideration should
be given to determinations of utility
capacity needs that could be
manipulated to limit renewable energy
procurements.592
586 CA
Cogeneration Comments at 10.
at 11.
588 Covanta Comments at 9.
589 Southeast Public Interest Organizations
Comments at 26.
590 Id. at 26–27.
591 Id. at 27.
592 Id. at 25–26.
587 Id.
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
54686
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
373. Mr. Mattson states that precedent
and legislative intent remove
competitive solicitations from being a
PPA option.593 Both Mr. Mattson and
Two Dot Wind point to the
Commission’s ruling in Hydrodynamics
that ‘‘requiring a QF to win a
competitive solicitation as a condition
to obtaining a long-term contract
imposes an unreasonable obstacle to
obtaining a legally enforceable
obligation.’’ 594 Two Dot Wind also
states that competitive solicitations have
not worked in Montana, and that the
NOPR’s suggestion that competitive
bidding can replace PURPA is not
supported by the factual record in
Montana.595
374. Industrial Energy Consumers
expresses concern that the parameters
for competitive solicitations are not
sufficiently developed to ensure a wellstructured, fairly administered,
transparent, and non-discriminatory
process for procurement, and therefore
opposes allowing a competitive
solicitation process to determine
avoided costs at this time.596
ii. Comments in Support
375. Several commenters support the
NOPR proposal to allow states the
ability to set energy and capacity rates
through a competitive solicitation such
as an RFP.597
376. Multiple commenters, including
EEI, NRECA, and the Oregon
Commission, support the notion that the
states are in the best position to tailor
the competitive solicitation process to
their needs, and that the Commission
should not provide detailed criteria
governing the use of competitive
solicitations.598 EEI states that the fact
that competitive solicitations may be
used to set avoided costs is an idea
nearly as old as PURPA.599 EEI also
supports the Commission’s proposal for
a state to allow a competitive
solicitation to be used as the exclusive
vehicle for acquiring QF capacity.600
NRECA notes that numerous NRECA
members have already had success
using competitive solicitations to
establish both energy and capacity rates
593 Mr.
Mattson Comments at 23.
Two Dot Wind Comments at 10 (citing
Hydrodynamics, 146 FERC ¶ 61,193).
595 Two Dot Wind Comments at 9–10.
596 Industrial Energy Consumers Comments at 13.
597 Alaska Power Comments at 1; Distributed Sun
Comments at 2; EEI Comments at 32–33; El Paso
Electric Comments at 4; NARUC Comments at 3;
NRECA Comments at 11; South Dakota Commission
Comments at 2–3.
598 EEI Comments at 32–33; NRECA Comments at
11; Oregon Commission Comments at 3–4.
599 EEI Comments at 32.
600 Id. at 33.
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
594 Id.;
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
in states where competitive solicitations
are permitted.601
377. Growth and Opportunity Center
states that competitive solicitation
processes, in place of avoided cost
calculations, provide better signals to
investors of where their electricity is
most valuable because competitive
solicitations reflect more informed
estimates of the real-time needs of
electricity consumers. Growth and
Opportunity Center contends that the
proposed rule changes, by giving states
more latitude to use competitive
solicitations in complying with PURPA,
should result in prices for consumers
that more accurately reflect market costs
for electricity.602 Growth and
Opportunity Center also asserts that in
states using competitive solicitation
processes, nondiscrimination rules
should be enforced to ensure that
solicitations are competitive and that no
providers receive preferential
treatment.603
378. The Michigan Commission states
that it recently approved using
competitive solicitations to determine
avoided capacity costs for a large
electric utility in Michigan.604 The
Michigan Commission states that it
believes that that recently approved
structure aligns with the Commission’s
proposal in the NOPR.605
379. Portland General asserts that,
because the output of an competitive
solicitation represents a resource’s true
market costs, a competitive solicitation
is the correct method to determine
avoided cost.606 Portland General states
that, given the competitive nature of
competitive solicitations, bidders are
highly motivated, which results in the
procurement of resources with high
benefit-to-cost ratios. Portland General
cites as an example its recent
competitive solicitation, which resulted
in a $40.70-levelized price and reflects
a combination of technologies (wind,
solar, and battery), whereas QFs, which
Portland General asserts provide lower
capacity, are currently offered at a
$45.19 levelized price for solar
energy.607
380. Xcel urges the Commission’s to
give the states the option of procuring
all needed capacity through competitive
bidding processes.608 Xcel strongly
believes that states must have the ability
to control capacity additions to ensure
601 NRECA
602 Growth
Comments at 11.
and Opportunity Center Comments at
that customer needs and state policy
goals are met.609 Xcel explains that in
many states, including some in which
the Xcel operating companies operate,
resource procurement is accomplished
largely through state-administered IRP
processes, which are utilized to ensure
a resource mix that meets the overall
public interest in affordable and clean
energy. Xcel states that these carefully
calibrated processes can be upset when
QFs bring capacity on to a utility’s
system that does not align with the
state’s vision of its optimal resource mix
and when those QFs also attempt to
collect above-market payments from
utilities and therefore customers. Xcel
states that Colorado’s procurement
efforts have been so successful that in
2016 more than 400 bids for 238 distinct
projects were submitted for Public
Service Company of Colorado alone,
and that this process resulted in some
of the lowest prices for renewables seen
as of that date, with a median wind
price of $19.30/MWh and a median
solar price of $30.96/MWh. Xcel argues
that unsolicited puts by QFs, in
contrast, can impede the ability of states
to meet their resource planning goals
and can undermine the competitive
markets that states like Colorado have
already created or are striving to
create.610
381. North Carolina Commission Staff
states that North Carolina has
implemented a competitive solicitation
process for solar energy that
complements the PURPA reforms
adopted by the state, with the first
solicitation concluding in April 2019.611
North Carolina Commission Staff states
that an independent administrator
estimated the initial nominal savings for
the competitive solicitation with a 20year contract versus traditional avoided
cost pricing to exceed $370 million for
the utilities involved.612
382. Duke Energy shares its statespecific experience with North
Carolina’s competitive solicitation for
renewable energy as a positive
example.613 Duke Energy states that
Duke Energy Carolinas, LLC and Duke
Energy Progress, LLC recently
completed their Tranche 1 Competitive
Procurement of Renewable Energy RFP
and procured approximately 550 MW of
new solar capacity for 20-year fixed
price contract terms at a projected
savings of approximately $261 million
relative to administratively determined
9.
603 Id.
at 10.
609 Id.
604 Michigan
605 Id.
Commission Comments at 4.
at 5.
606 Portland
General Comments at 11.
607 Id.
608 Xcel
PO 00000
Comments at 10.
Frm 00050
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
at 8.
at 9.
611 North Carolina Commission Staff Comments at
3–4.
612 Id. at 4.
613 Duke Energy Comments at 10–12.
610 Id.
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
forecasts of avoided costs over this same
period.614
iii. Comments Requesting
Modifications/Clarifications
(a) Requests for Clarification and/or
Separate Proceedings
383. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA
argue that the NOPR fails to explain (1)
whether the Commission is proposing to
merely clarify that a state could use the
lowest offer prices submitted in a
competitive solicitation to set the
avoided costs of energy and capacity on
a prospective basis for any QF seeking
a contract until the next competitive
solicitation, or (2) whether the
Commission is proposing a radical
change in its precedent by revising its
rules to provide that a QF may only sell
under a long-term contract if that QF
wins a competitive solicitation, which
NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA assert
would be contrary to the
Hydrodynamics 615 and Winding
Creek 616 cases.617
384. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA
request that any requirement to win a
competitive solicitation to obtain a longterm PURPA contract should exempt
small facilities.618 NIPPC, CREA, REC,
and OSEIA further state that the
Commission should: (1) Require that the
competitive solicitation include no
utility-ownership options; or (2) if
utility-owned generation may result, the
competitive solicitation must be: (i)
Administered and scored (not just
overseen) by a qualified independent
party, not the utility; (ii) any utility or
utility-affiliate ownership bid must be
capped at its bid price and not allowed
traditional cost-plus ratemaking
treatment; and (iii) the product sought,
minimum bidding criteria, and detailed
scoring criteria must be made known to
all parties at the same time.619
Additionally, NIPPC, CREA, REC, and
OSEIA contend that an option for longterm contracts should remain available
for both small QFs and existing QFs
outside of a competitive solicitation.620
385. The Michigan Commission states
that it would welcome guidance on
whether, and under what
circumstances, a competitive
solicitation can be used as a utility’s
exclusive vehicle for acquiring QF
capacity.621 Similarly, the Montana
Commission recommends that the
Commission provide as much guidance
to states as possible regarding the
requirements for transparency and nondiscrimination.622
386. The California Commission states
that the NOPR does not provide states
any more flexibility than they already
have, and the Commission’s final order
adopting revised regulations should
clearly state this.623
387. Several commenters suggest that
the Commission should conduct
focused additional processes on this
topic.624 Advanced Energy Economy
suggests that the Commission conduct
one or more workshops or technical
conferences, to explore in detail the
specific factors that would make a
utility competitive solicitation process a
truly competitive process of a
‘‘comparative quality’’ to competitive
wholesale energy and capacity
markets.625 Advanced Energy Economy
contends that such workshops or
technical conferences could ultimately
be the basis for developing proposed
regulations better guiding the states and
electric utilities in implementing open
and competitive solicitation processes
to obtain relief from the mandatory
purchase obligation under PURPA
section 210(m)(1)(C).626 Industrial
Energy Consumers argues that, if the
Commission seeks to allow states to rely
on competitive solicitation processes,
the Commission should undertake a
separate inquiry, with necessary
technical conferences, to develop
specific parameters to govern such
processes.627 If the Commission relies
directly on competitive solicitation
processes in the final rule, Industrial
Energy Consumers states that if, after
undertaking the competitive
solicitation, the utility rejects all offers
and decides to self-build, then the allinclusive price of the self-build option
should at least establish the avoided
cost rate for QFs seeking to develop in
that area.628 EPSA argues that the
Commission should require further
proceedings, including another
technical conference, to discuss the
protections that would be necessary in
order to have a genuinely level playing
field for competitive solicitations.629
388. Commissioner Slaughter states
that PURPA sits at the intersection of
competition and regulatory policy in an
area of vital and urgent interest, and that
the Commission should establish fair,
non-discriminatory guidelines for
competitive solicitations that would
help states and other stakeholders
maximize the benefits of competition
from low-cost energy sources,
particularly utility-scale renewable
energy facilities.630 Commissioner
Slaughter states that such guidelines
could form the basis for transitioning
many local markets from
administratively determined prices to
environments of dynamic price
discovery in which the rapidly
decreasing cost of utility-scale
renewable energy can put maximum
pressure on both new and pre-existing
fossil fuel-based sources of
electricity.631
389. EPSA states that the Commission
should ensure that competitive
solicitations are properly designed to
ensure that QFs have meaningful
opportunities to compete against
resources owned by incumbent utilities
on a level playing field.632 EPSA states
that the Commission should use this
opportunity to do a full assessment of
how competitive solicitations are
working and could be enhanced, while
providing continued protections to
prevent discrimination against QFs.633
EPSA also emphasizes that, regardless
of whatever competitive solicitation
rules the Commission ultimately adopts,
the Commission must continue to
exercise its ‘‘backstop’’ oversight and
enforcement authority to ensure that
any requirements are implemented in a
consistent and appropriate manner by
individual states.634
(b) Requests Regarding Proposed
Criteria
390. Several commenters requested
that the Commission clarify the criteria
that solicitations be conducted at
regular intervals.635 Several commenters
request that the Commission reconsider
or remove that criteria.636 sPower argues
that the Commission should require that
such competitive solicitations be
conducted at a minimum every two
years.637 Colorado Independent Energy
622 Montana
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
614 Id.
at 12.
615 Hydrodynamics, 146 FERC ¶ 61,193.
616 Winding Creek Solar LLC v. Peterman, 932
F.3d 861.
617 NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at
62–63.
618 Id. at 67.
619 Id.
620 Id. at 67–68.
621 Michigan Commission Comments at 5.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
Commission Comments at 3.
Commission Comments at 23.
624 Advanced Energy Economy Comments at 13;
EPSA Comments at 15–16; Industrial Energy
Consumers Comments at 13–14.
625 Advanced Energy Economy Comments at 13.
626 Id.
627 Industrial Energy Consumers Comments at 13–
14.
628 Id. at 14.
629 EPSA Comments at 16.
54687
623 California
PO 00000
Frm 00051
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
630 Commissioner
Slaughter Comments at 1–2.
at 3.
632 EPSA Comments at 3.
633 Id. at 14.
634 Id. at 16–17.
635 APPA Comments at 17–18; Basin Comments at
9; Montana Commission Comments at 3; sPower
Comments at 9–10.
636 NorthWestern Comments at 7–8.
637 sPower Comments at 9–10.
631 Id.
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
54688
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
asserts that competitive solicitations
should be held at regular intervals to
test the market, and that the
Commission should consider the entire
market, not just projects 80 MW and
under, in evaluating whether there are
full and competitive opportunities.638
391. Several commenters oppose the
requirement for an independent
administrator.639 APPA argues that the
entire PURPA administrative construct
is designed to entrust to state regulatory
authorities the responsibility to carry
out the duties they are assigned under
the Commission’s regulations.640
NRECA believes that states are in the
best position to determine the need for
‘‘oversight by an independent
administrator’’ and recommends this
criterion be deleted.641 NRECA requests
that, if the Commission retains the
requirement that competitive
solicitation processes include some type
of oversight, instead of requiring
oversight by an independent
administrator, the Commission should
allow states the flexibility to allow
electric utilities to retain a third-party
consultant for this purpose.642 NRECA
contends that many cooperatives have
long-standing relationships with thirdparty consultants that assist the
cooperatives in evaluating power supply
options, and requiring those
cooperatives to now use some other
entity (i.e., the independent
administrator) would be disruptive and
costly.643 Colorado Independent Energy
notes that, while independent
evaluators are helpful, they are often
employed by utilities and thus
sometimes reluctant to offer third party
criticism of the bid evaluation
process.644
392. The Montana Commission
requests clarification of the term
‘‘independent administrator’’ and
‘‘certified’’ as those terms are used in
the proposed revisions to
§ 292.304(b).645
393. sPower disagrees that a
competitive solicitation should ‘‘take
into account the required operating
characteristics of the needed capacity’’
in order to produce accurate avoided
cost rates and recommends that a final
638 Colorado
Independent Energy Comments at 9–
12.
639 APPA
Comments at 18; NRECA Comments at
rule remove that language from
condition (ii) in the Commission’s list of
conditions that a competitive
solicitation must meet.646
394. Colorado Independent Energy
states that, in addition to the guidelines
provided in the NOPR, the Commission
should include additional guidelines,
including that fairness of an ‘‘allsource’’ competitive solicitation must
also be determined based on bid
evaluation and not just on a competitive
solicitation. Colorado Independent
Energy asserts that competitive
solicitation submissions can be
technology-specific, but not the
evaluation or the analysis of the need to
be met by a competitive solicitation.
Colorado Independent Energy asserts
that a true all-source selection process
must allow resource planning models to
optimize among all bids received
without bias toward QF-eligible
technologies such as renewable
generation or cogeneration.647
395. Several commenters stated that
competitive solicitations must be
assessed using the criteria set forth in
Allegheny.648 EPSA further states that,
while the Allegheny principles provide
a good starting point, additional
protections will be required to level the
playing field between independent
generators and utilities.649 R Street
asserts that, if an auction can meet the
Allegheny standard, then generators in
that state would not be eligible for QF
designations. R Street suggests that QFs
should not be able to force their power
on utilities if they lose such fairly
administered auctions.650
396. Solar Energy Industries asserts
that the Commission should require a
purchasing electric utility to provide the
state commission, and make available
for public inspection, a post-solicitation
report that: (1) Identifies the winning
bidders; (2) includes a copy of any
reports issued by the independent
evaluator; and (3) demonstrates that the
solicitation program was implemented
without undue preference for the
interests of the purchasing utility or its
affiliates. Solar Energy Industries further
assert that the solicitation program
should include clear details regarding
the manner in which the bids will be
scored and clearly specify price and
non-price criteria under which bids are
evaluated including: (1) Acceptable
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
11.
640 APPA Comments at 18 (citing 16 U.S.C. 824a–
3(f) (expressly calling for state regulatory authorities
and nonregulated electric utilities to implement
Commission-issued PURPA regulations)).
641 NRECA Comments at 11.
642 Id. at 12.
643 Id.
644 Colorado Independent Energy Comments at 8.
645 Montana Commission Comments at 3.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
646 sPower
Comments at 8.
Independent Energy at 2.
648 EPSA Comments at 14–15 (citing Allegheny,
108 FERC ¶ 61,082); R Street Comments at 3–4;
Solar Energy Industries Supplemental Comments,
Docket No. AD16–16–000, at 32–37 (filed Aug. 28,
2019).
649 EPSA Comments at 15.
650 R Street Comments at 3–4.
647 Colorado
PO 00000
Frm 00052
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
delivery points and any scoring
deductions for delivery to other points;
(2) credit evaluation criteria and
development securing requirements;
and (3) performance requirements.651
397. Public Interest Organizations
argue that the Commission’s proposal
does not require that state competitive
solicitation procedures meet the
statutory floor established through
PURPA that rates both (1) encourage
small power producers and (2) not
discriminate relative to the utility’s own
generation and other non-QF
generators.652 To ensure competitive
solicitations actually meet the statutory
criteria, the Commission must ensure
that competitive solicitations meet four
minimum standards.653 First, Public
Interest Organizations state that
solicitations must account for utilityowned and non-QF generation and
cannot be a limited competition
between QFs without the ability to
displace non-QF generation.654 As an
example of an incorrectly-conducted,
and unlawfully-discriminatory, bidding
process, Public Interest Organizations
cite the Nevada competitive solicitation
process that is limited to QFs to meet a
small, segregated portion of the utility’s
energy and unmet capacity
requirements.655 Second, to ensure that
QFs receive the same price that other
generation receives, Public Interest
Organizations state that all sources of
supply must compete in the competitive
solicitation— including the utility’s
own generation.656 Third, Public
Interest Organizations state that the
solicitation process cannot be used in
any way to curtail or delay a utility’s
obligation to purchase from QFs.657
Fourth, the ‘‘required operating
characteristics of the needed capacity’’
factor suggested in the NOPR cannot be
used as a surrogate to define
characteristics of only non-QF
generation or to allow a utility to pick
among favored generators.658
398. Biogas states that, if QFs are to
enter into competitive solicitations as a
vehicle for PURPA, then there must be
some correcting for the inequitable tax
and regulatory provisions afforded to
incumbent utilities and select renewable
651 Solar Energy Industries Supplemental
Comments, Docket No. AD16–16–000, at 21 (filed
August 28, 2019).
652 Public Interest Organizations Comments at 69–
70.
653 Id. at 70.
654 Id.
655 Id. at 71–72.
656 Id. at 72.
657 Id. at 72–73.
658 Id. at 73.
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
technologies, in order to ensure a fair
market opportunity.659
399. American Dams requests that
QFs competing against a utility that can
rate base the cost of new generation
should be entitled to similar valuation
provided that QF costs are at or less
than those of the utility.660
(c) Other Requests
400. In their comments to the NOPR,
Solar Energy Industries reference their
August 28, 2019 comments in Docket
No. AD16–16–000,661 in which they
describe the ‘‘SEIA Counterproposal.’’
That document proposes that, where a
utility seeks to meet identified capacity
needs through an open, fairly designed,
and independently administered
competitive solicitation: (i) The
purchasing electric utility would only
have to pay QFs for capacity to the
extent that the purchasing electric
utility failed to meet identified need
through the competitive solicitation;
and (ii) the QF would be paid for its
output (energy and capacity) at the
market rate established through the
competitive solicitation process.662
401. Solar Energy Industries request
that the Commission supplement
proposed 18 CFR 292.304(b)(5) to
require that: (1) Participants are
provided with complete and transparent
information regarding transmission
constraints, levels of congestion, and
interconnections; and (2) the solicitation
is linked with the purchasing utility’s
IRP and is conducted for the entirety of
a utility’s anticipated capacity needs.663
402. Solar Energy Industries request
that the Commission expressly
implement safeguards to prevent utility
self-dealing and affiliate abuse, with
regard to both price and non-price
terms.664 Solar Energy Industries
reference their previous comments in
this proceeding, which they state
describe practices of PacifiCorp,665
NorthWestern,666 Duke,667 and Xcel 668
purportedly showing that these utilities
have attempted to reduce QFs’ ability to
sell while simultaneously seeking to
build and rate base their own
substantial renewable resources.669
659 Biogas
Comments at 2.
Dams Comments at 3.
661 Solar Energy Industries Supplemental
Comments, Docket No. AD16–16–000, at 17–40
(filed Aug. 28, 2019).
662 Solar Energy Industries Comments at 38.
663 Id. at 39.
664 Id.
665 Solar Energy Industries Supplemental
Comments, Docket No. AD16–16–000, at 25–28
(filed August 28, 2019).
666 Id. at 28–29.
667 Id. at 29–31.
668 Id. at 21.
669 Solar Energy Industries Comments at 40.
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
660 American
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
403. ELCON states that it continues to
see shortcomings in competitive
procurement practices across regions.670
A current example ELCON provides is
Dominion Energy Virginia’s 2019 RFP
which, ELCON argues, limited
competition in a manner that all but
guarantees that a Dominion self-build
option will prevail because it restricts
participation to new resources only and
does not permit an independent third
party to evaluate bids.671 Another
example ELCON provides is a recent
Entergy Louisiana solicitation through
which a natural gas generating facility
was approved despite opposition from
Louisiana industrial consumers who
argued that the competitive solicitation
was improperly designed to limit
resource options to new construction
comparable to a self-build.672
404. ELCON asserts that, to be
competitive, a competitive solicitation
must be transparent, face independent
oversight, have safeguards against
affiliate abuse involving transactions
between franchised utilities and their
market-based affiliates, and have welldefined technical parameters.673 ELCON
states that experiences with competitive
solicitations thus far expose the
challenges of achieving a workably
competitive process. ELCON urges the
Commission to set a high bar, with
enforcement to verify that a process is
sufficiently competitive.674
405. NorthWestern states that it
supports the Commission’s proposal to
use competitive solicitations or RFPs to
establish avoided capacity costs, but not
avoided energy costs, because
NorthWestern believes that an energyonly competitive solicitation has no
relation to the market whereas a
capacity competitive solicitation
does.675 NorthWestern believes that use
of a competitive solicitation should be
the preferred vehicle for setting avoided
capacity rates for QFs because this will
ensure that the capacity is acquired at
the least cost thereby benefiting
customers.676
406. Institute for Energy Research
states that it would go even further than
the NOPR proposal and require that
competitive solicitations be the default
whenever possible, with states having to
justify case-by-case why a noncompetitive solicitation is needed,
because solicitation is the best
670 ELCON
Comments at 27.
671 Id.
672 Id.
673 Id.
at 28.
at 28–29.
674 Id.
675 NorthWestern
Comments at 7.
676 Id.
PO 00000
Frm 00053
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
54689
expression of the Congressional
mandate to encourage competition.677
407. Harvard Electricity Law states
that the NOPR’s proposed 18 CFR
292.304(b)(8)(ii), requiring solicitations
must be open to ‘‘all sources’’—could be
read as inconsistent with the
Commission’s CPUC orders 678 and the
2019 CARE v. CPUC decision.679
Harvard Electricity Law argues that, if
the Commission amends its avoided
cost rules to allow states to set avoided
cost rates based on competitive
solicitations, it should clarify that states
may set tiered rates, as the Commission
and the U.S. Court of Appeals for the
Ninth Circuit has allowed in the above
cases.680
408. The Oregon Commission
recommends that the Commission
emphasize the need for states to have
adequate safeguards to protect bidders’
confidential and commercially sensitive
proprietary information when using
competitive solicitations to determine or
inform avoided cost rates.681
409. sPower states that the issue of
using a competitive solicitation process
to establish avoided cost rates has
sometimes been conflated with using a
competitive solicitation process to
establish a LEO, and sPower encourages
the Commission to continue to analyze
these distinct issues separately.682
410. Resources for the Future stresses
that competitive solicitations alone
would minimize QF costs but would not
establish avoided cost rates, which
depend on much more than the cost of
QF generation.683 However, used in
concert with forward curves, Resources
for the Future states that competitive
solicitations could provide an effective
complementary method.684
c. Commission Determination
411. In this final rule, we affirm the
NOPR proposal to revise the PURPA
Regulations to explicitly permit a state
the flexibility to set avoided energy and/
or capacity rates using competitive
solicitations (i.e., RFPs), conducted
677 Institute
for Energy Research Comments at 1.
Pub. Utils. Comm’n, 133 FERC ¶ 61,059,
clarification and reh’g denied, 133 FERC ¶ 61,059
(2010), reh’g denied, 134 FERC ¶ 61,044 (2011)
(CPUC) .
679 Californians for Renewable Energy v. Cal. Pub.
Utils. Comm’n, 922 F.3d 929, 937 (9th Cir. 2019)
(CARE v. CPUC) (holding that ‘‘where a state has
[a renewable portfolio standard (RPS)] and the
utility is using a QF’s energy to meet the RPS, the
utility cannot calculate avoided costs based on
energy sources that would not also meet the RPS[,]’’
which ‘‘comports with PURPA’s goal to put QFs on
an equal footing with other energy providers’’).
680 Harvard Electricity Law Comments at 31.
681 Oregon Commission Comments at 4.
682 sPower Comments at 3.
683 Resources for the Future Comments at 8–9.
684 Id. at 9.
678 Cal.
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
54690
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
pursuant to appropriate procedures in a
transparent and non-discriminatory
manner. A primary feature of a
transparent and non-discriminatory
competitive solicitation is that a utility’s
capacity needs are open for bidding to
all capacity providers, including QF and
non-QF resources, on a level playing
field. This level playing field ensures
that any QF’s capacity rates that result
from the competitive solicitation are just
and reasonable and non-discriminatory
avoided cost rates.
412. Consistent with our general
approach of giving states flexibility in
the manner in which they determine
avoided costs, we do not prescribe
detailed criteria governing the use of
competitive solicitations as tools to
determine rates to be paid to QFs, as
well as to determine other contract
terms. States arguably are in the best
position to consider their particular
local circumstances, including
questions of need, resulting economic
impacts, amounts to be purchased
through auctions, and related issues.
413. In considering what constitutes
proper design and administration of a
competitive solicitation, however, we
find it appropriate to establish certain
minimum criteria governing the process
by which competitive solicitations are
to be conducted in order for an
competitive solicitation to be used to set
QF rates. These factors, which we
proposed in the NOPR and adopt here,
include, among others: (a) An open and
transparent process; (b) solicitations
should be open to all sources to satisfy
that purchasing electric utility’s
capacity needs, taking into account the
required operating characteristics of the
needed capacity; (c) solicitations
conducted at regular intervals; (d)
oversight by an independent
administrator; and (e) certification as
fulfilling the above criteria by the state
regulatory authority or nonregulated
electric utility.
414. We affirm that such competitive
solicitations must be conducted in a
process that includes, but is not limited
to, the factors identified above that will
be set forth in 18 CFR 292.304(b)(8).
This rule does not undo any competitive
solicitations conducted prior to the
effective date of this final rule that may
not have met these criteria. This rule
applies only to competitive solicitations
conducted after the effective date of the
final rule. We also provide
modifications and clarifications to the
NOPR proposal, as described below.
i. Requests for Clarification and/or
Separate Proceedings
415. As an initial matter, in the
NOPR, the Commission addressed
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
competitive solicitations in two related
but distinct contexts. The first, to be
discussed in this section, relates to the
proposal to explicitly permit a state the
flexibility to set avoided cost energy
and/or capacity rates using competitive
solicitations (i.e., RFPs), conducted
pursuant to appropriate procedures. The
second, to be discussed below, in
section IV.G.2 of this final rule,
concerns the NARUC proposal that
urged the Commission to give meaning
to PURPA section 210m(1)(C) by
establishing a ‘‘yardstick’’ by which a
vertically integrated utility outside of an
RTO or ISO could apply to terminate the
mandatory purchase obligation if it
conducts sufficiently competitive RFPs
for energy or capacity.
416. More generally, we support the
use of competitive solicitations as a
means to foster competition in the
procurement of generation and to
encourage the development of QFs in a
way that most accurately reflects a
purchasing utility’s avoided costs. We
believe that allowing QFs to compete to
provide capacity and energy needs,
through a properly administered
competitive solicitation, may help
ensure an accurate determination of the
purchasing electric utility’s avoided
cost, and therefore result in prices
meeting the PURPA’s statutory
requirements. We also believe that it is
reasonable for states to choose to require
QFs to be responsive to price signals as
to where and when capacity is needed.
We believe that a properly
administered competitive solicitation
can help provide such price signals.
417. Furthermore, we believe that
competitive solicitations may be an
especially appropriate tool for
developing competition in the markets
outside of RTOs and ISOs, where there
are no organized competitive markets in
place where QFs can make sales.
418. We emphasize, however, that
neither the Commission’s current
regulations, nor those adopted in this
final rule, require a state or a purchasing
electric utility to use a competitive
solicitation to determine avoided cost
rates for QFs. Consistent with other
changes in our regulations discussed
above, we give states the flexibility to
use a properly structured competitive
solicitation for this purpose, but we do
not mandate that they do so.
419. Furthermore, in light of the
substantial experience the industry has
with competitive solicitations within
and outside of the PURPA context, and
the voluminous comments the
Commission has received regarding
competitive solicitations, we find that
there is not currently a need for a
separate proceeding or additional
PO 00000
Frm 00054
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
procedures to address competitive
solicitation issues, such as holding
workshops or technical conferences.
Should further procedures appear
beneficial in light of actual competitive
solicitation experience under PURPA
and the regulations adopted today, such
a proceeding may be appropriate in the
future.
ii. Proposed Criteria
420. We continue to find that
competitive solicitations as discussed in
this final rule may accurately reflect a
purchasing electric utility’s avoided
costs and ensure that the resulting rates
for winners of such competitive
solicitations are consistent with PURPA.
A competitive solicitation may more
accurately value QF capacity over time
by subjecting it to competition with
other sources. Such competitive
solicitations may provide more certainty
both to QFs regarding when and how
often they will be eligible to compete
and to purchasing utilities regarding
how they may expect to fulfill their
capacity needs.
421. The Commission clarifies that, if
a utility acquires all of its capacity
through properly conducted competitive
solicitations (using the factors described
above), and does not add capacity
through self-building and purchasing
power from other sources outside of
such solicitations, the competitive
solicitations could be the exclusive
vehicle for the purchasing electric
utility to pay avoided capacity costs
from a QF. In this situation, using
properly conducted competitive
solicitations as the exclusive vehicle to
determine the purchasing electric
utility’s avoided cost capacity rates
would allow QFs a chance to compete
to provide the utility’s capacity needs
on a level playing field with the utility.
We clarify that it is up to the states to
determine whether to require that a
utility’s total planned self-build and
power purchase options must compete
in the competitive solicitations, and we
will not direct such a requirement here.
422. If a state decides to require utility
self-build and power purchase options
to participate in competitive
solicitations, then a QF that does not
obtain an award in a competitive
solicitation would have no right to an
avoided cost capacity rate more than
zero because the utility’s full capacity
needs would have been met by the
competitive solicitation.685 However,
685 This would be consistent with City of
Ketchikan, 94 FERC at 62,061 (‘‘[A]voided cost rates
need not include the cost for capacity in the event
that the utility’s demand (or need) for capacity is
zero. That is, when the demand for capacity is zero,
the cost for capacity may also be zero.’’).
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
QFs would continue to have the right to
put energy to the utility at the asavailable avoided cost energy rate
because the purchasing utility will still
be able to avoid incurring the cost of
generating energy even when it does not
need new capacity.
423. If the state does not require
utility self-build and purchase options
to participate in competitive
solicitations, then QFs that lose in a
competitive solicitation still may have
the right to avoided cost capacity rates
more than zero if the state determines
that the utility still has capacity needs
after the competitive solicitation that
otherwise could be met through the
utility’s self-build or purchase options.
424. The Commission has held and
we reaffirm here that, when capacity is
not needed, the avoided capacity cost
rate can be zero.686 Competitive
solicitations conducted pursuant to the
rules adopted in this final rule that are
held whenever capacity is needed
provide QFs a level playing field on
which to compete to sell capacity. This
approach further shields purchasing
electric utilities from situations like
those explained by Xcel, where QFs
could simply sit out the competitive
solicitation process (or participate but
not have their bids accepted), but then
seek to sell capacity to the purchasing
electric utility and to receive a separate
higher administratively-determined
avoided cost rate including an avoided
cost capacity rate, and even potentially
displace non-QF competitive
solicitation winners.687 This approach
benefits ratepayers because allowing
QFs to compete in properly conducted,
competitive solicitations that are held
whenever capacity is needed allows the
purchasing utility to obtain needed
capacity efficiently. To be clear, the
competitive solicitation is not to be a
means to determine a QF’s right to put
as-available energy to the utility. But the
competitive solicitation can be the
means to determine what, if any, rate
the QF will be paid for capacity.
425. Multiple commenters point out
that using competitive solicitations
could be a beneficial way to carry out
the Congressional intent behind PURPA.
However, many of these same
commenters claim that the competitive
solicitations carried out to date do not
live up to this standard. In other words,
commenters assert that the competitive
solicitations conducted to date have
often not been properly conducted and
instead have been unfair. As described
above, assertions about specific states’
competitive solicitation processes
include that:
—The competitive solicitations
conducted in Florida are unfair
because they do not require an
Independent Evaluator as part of the
competitive solicitation process; 688
—the competitive solicitations
conducted in Colorado and Oklahoma
are unfair because purchasing electric
utilities are allowed to apply for
waivers of the competitive solicitation
requirement; 689
—The competitive solicitations
conducted in North Carolina are
unfair because the incumbent
purchasing electric utility can receive
preferential treatment in the form of
waivers of the post bid security
otherwise required for any
independently owned projects; 690
and
—The competitive solicitations
conducted in Nevada are unfair
because the process is limited to QFs
to meet a small, segregated portion of
the utility’s energy and unmet
capacity requirements.691
426. Commenters also make assertions
about unfair practices of purchasing
electric utilities, including that the
purchasing electric utilities have
attempted to reduce QFs’ ability to sell
while the purchasing electric utilities
are simultaneously seeking to build and
rate base their own substantial
renewable resources.
427. The criteria proposed in the
NOPR were aimed at ensuring that
competitive solicitations are conducted
fairly. In this final rule, the Commission
finds that, in order to use the results of
a competitive solicitation to set avoided
cost rates, the competitive solicitation
must be conducted in a transparent and
non-discriminatory manner. Such a
competitive solicitation must be
conducted in a process that includes,
but is not limited to, the following
factors: (i) The solicitation process is an
open and transparent process that
includes, but is not limited to, providing
equally to all potential bidders
substantial and meaningful information
regarding transmission constraints,
levels of congestion, and
interconnections, subject to appropriate
confidentiality safeguards; (ii)
solicitations must be open to all sources,
to satisfy that purchasing electric
686 Id. at 62,061 (‘‘[A]voided cost rates need not
include the cost for capacity in the event that the
utility’s demand (or need) for capacity is zero. That
is, when the demand for capacity is zero, the cost
for capacity may also be zero.’’).
687 See Xcel Comments at 2–3, 9–10.
688 Southeast Public Interest Organizations
Comments at 27.
689 Id.
690 Id.
691 Public Interest Organizations Comments at 71–
72.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
PO 00000
Frm 00055
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
54691
utility’s capacity needs, taking into
account the required operating
characteristics of the needed capacity;
(iii) solicitations are conducted at
regular intervals; (iv) solicitations are
subject to oversight by an independent
administrator; and (v) solicitations are
certified as fulfilling the above criteria
by the relevant state regulatory authority
or nonregulated electric utility through
a post-solicitation report.
428. Without judging the competitive
solicitations conducted to date, we find
that henceforth any competitive
solicitation that does not comply with
these factors will be viewed as not
transparent and discriminatory, and not
a basis for either setting the avoided cost
capacity rate that a QF may charge the
purchasing electric utility or limiting
which generators can receive a capacity
rate. Phrased differently, we will
presume that any future competitive
solicitation that does not comply with
the factors adopted in this final rule
does not comply with the Commission’s
regulations implementing PURPA.
429. In addition, to further promote
fairness, the Commission makes several
clarifications, as described below.
430. We clarify that competitive
solicitations must also be conducted in
accordance with the Allegheny
principles under which the Commission
evaluates a competitive solicitation: (1)
Transparency, a requirement that the
solicitation process be open and fair; (2)
definition, a requirement that the
product, or products, sought through the
competitive solicitation be precisely
defined; (3) evaluation, a requirement
that the evaluation criteria be
standardized and applied equally to all
bids and bidders; and (4) oversight, a
requirement that an independent third
party design the solicitation, administer
bidding, and evaluate bids prior to
selection.692 While the NOPR’s
proposed guidelines for competitive
solicitations were generally inclusive of
the Allegheny principles, in order to
more precisely define what is and what
is not a properly conducted competitive
solicitation that can be used to
determine what generators will be
entitled to an avoided cost capacity rate,
and what that rate will be, we
specifically clarify here that the
Allegheny principles apply as well.
431. We also revise the proposed
language in 18 CFR 292.304(d)(8)(i) to
clarify that participants must be
provided with substantial and
meaningful information regarding
transmission constraints, levels of
congestion, and interconnections,
subject to appropriate confidentiality
692 Allegheny,
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
108 FERC ¶ 61,082 at P 18.
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
54692
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
safeguards. We believe that it is
important that all participants in the
competitive solicitation have access to
these data as a necessary predicate for
a nondiscriminatory competitive
solicitation process, and we find that
requiring that this information be
provided will help ensure that a
competitive solicitation is open and
transparent. We acknowledge the risk
that competitive solicitation
participants could use this information
to gain a competitive advantage that
could be used outside of the competitive
solicitation, but find that this risk can be
minimized through the use of nondisclosure agreements and placing
reasonable limits on those persons
permitted to review the information,
just as is done in other Commission
proceedings where this issue arises.
432. We also clarify that the
requirement that the competitive
solicitation process be open and
transparent includes that the electric
utility provide the state commission,
and make available for public
inspection, a post-solicitation report
that: (1) Identifies the winning bidders;
(2) includes a copy of any reports issued
by the independent evaluator; and (3)
demonstrates that the solicitation
program was implemented without
undue preference for the interests of the
purchasing utility or its affiliates. We
find this consistent with the
requirement that competitive
solicitations be open and transparent, to
not only ensure that utilities are not
discriminating against QFs, but also to
help all stakeholders and the public at
large better understand the utility’s
competitive solicitation processes and
thus to be confident in the fairness of
the process and of the results.
433. Regarding the requirement that
solicitations must be open to all sources
to satisfy the purchasing electric
utility’s capacity needs, taking into
account the required operating
characteristics of the needed capacity,
we decline to remove the phrase ‘‘taking
into account the operating
characteristics of the needed capacity.’’
There may be times when a utility needs
capacity with specific attributes, such as
specific ramping capability, that cannot
be filled by certain types of generators.
However, we agree with Public Interest
Organizations that this phrase may not
be used to define characteristics of only
non-QF generation or to allow a utility
to select favored generators.693
434. We decline to be overly
prescriptive as to what constitutes
‘‘regular intervals.’’ In general, utilities
should be reviewing their capacity
693 Public
Interest Organizations Comments at 73.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
needs frequently, and the state or
nonregulated electric utility is in the
best position to determine the frequency
of that review. However, there may be
times when a utility’s review of capacity
needs reveals that no capacity is
needed, and it would not make sense for
a competitive solicitation to be
mandated at such a time.
435. We similarly decline to be overly
prescriptive as to what constitutes an
‘‘independent administrator.’’
Commenters argue on both sides
whether the NOPR proposal goes too far
or not far enough. On the one hand,
NRECA argues that states are in the best
position to determine the need for
oversight by an independent
administrator and recommends this
criterion be deleted.694 On the other
hand, Colorado Independent Energy
notes that independent administrators
are often employed by utilities and thus
sometimes reluctant to offer third party
criticism of the bid evaluation
process.695 We clarify that the
independent administrator, who is
responsible for administering the
competitive solicitation, must be an
entity independent from the purchasing
electric utility in order to help ensure
fairness. Whether the entity is called an
independent administrator or a thirdparty consultant, the substantive
requirement of this factor is that the
competitive solicitation not be
administered by the purchasing electric
utility itself or its affiliates, but rather by
a separate, unbiased, and unaffiliated
entity not subject to being influenced by
the purchasing utility. We recognize,
however, that such an independent
administrator will need to be selected
and paid. Though we are not directing
a process, we note that the selection and
payment could be done under the
auspices of a state regulatory authority
or by mutual agreement between the
utility and the competitive solicitation
participants.
436. In response to the Montana
Commission’s request for clarification as
to what ‘‘certified’’ means within the
guideline that requires certification of
the competitive solicitation by the state
regulatory authority or nonregulated
electric utility as fulfilling the above
694 NRECA Comments at 11. In this final rule, we
note, for ease of readability we have used the word
‘‘state’’ to refer to both state regulatory authorities
and to nonregulated electric utilities. Thus, in the
context of nonregulated electric utilities in
particular, to say that the ‘‘state’’ can fairly
administer the competitive solicitation is to say that
the nonregulated electric utility can, essentially, be
both the purchasing electric utility and potentially
the independent administrator of its own
competitive solicitation. That is a result we cannot
countenance.
695 Colorado Independent Energy Comments at 8.
PO 00000
Frm 00056
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
criteria, we clarify that, after a thorough
review of the competitive solicitation
procedures used and the competitive
solicitation results, certification of the
competitive solicitation requires a
written, formally-issued finding by the
state that the competitive solicitation
and its results comply with PURPA and
this Commission’s PURPA regulations—
and must include the independent
administrator’s report to the same effect.
437. We decline at this time to add
any additional requirements for
competitive solicitations. We continue
to believe that states may be in the best
position to consider their particular
local circumstances. We think that the
guidelines adopted here, in conjunction
with the Allegheny principles and other
clarifications made here, provide an
adequate framework for competitive
solicitations to be conducted efficiently,
transparently and in a
nondiscriminatory manner.
438. We also clarify that, if a
competitive solicitation is not
conducted fairly and in accordance with
the guidelines here, then an aggrieved
entity may challenge the state’s
competitive solicitation in the
appropriate forum, which could include
any one or more of the following: (1)
Initiating or participating in proceedings
before the relevant state commission or
governing body; (2) filing for judicial
review of any state regulatory
proceeding in state court (under PURPA
section 210(g)); or, alternatively (3)
filing a petition for enforcement against
the state at the Commission and, if the
Commission declines to act, later filing
a petition against the state in U.S.
district court (under PURPA section
210(h)(2)(B)).
iii. Other Requests
439. We decline to grant Solar Energy
Industries request to require that
solicitations be linked with the
purchasing electric utility’s IRP. Where
a state has an IRP,696 it may make sense
to link the competitive solicitation
processes with the IRP so that the
competitive solicitation is conducted for
the entirety of a utility’s anticipated
capacity needs. On the other hand, IRPs
may come in a variety of forms. For
example, an IRP may merely be a
general projection of short- and longterm load growth and potential
resources to meet such growth, and each
generation project may be subject to
specific approval based on actual
specific need. In order to provide states
flexibility in conducting these
696 16 U.S.C. 2621(a), (d)(7) (requiring states to
consider whether to employ integrated resource
planning).
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
processes, we will not require such
links between competitive solicitations
and IRPs, although such links certainly
are permitted if a state deems it to be
appropriate.
440. Regarding facilities not designed
primarily to sell electricity to the
purchasing electric utility, such as
waste to power small power production
facilities and cogeneration facilities, we
find that an exemption from competitive
solicitation processes is unnecessary.
We do not exempt small power
production facilities from the
competitive solicitation process; we are
not persuaded that such an exemption
is appropriate given that exempting
large classes of small power producers
could frustrate the price discovery
function of the competitive solicitation.
A large number of exempted small
facilities could disrupt the competitive
solicitation process. We clarify,
however, that QFs whose capacity is
100 kW or less already are entitled to
standard rates regardless of whether
they compete in a competitive
solicitation and we do not change that
regulation in this final rule.697 Given
that we view competitive solicitations
as an important price discovery tool and
that states already are required to
establish standard rates for such
entities, there is no need to determine
prices for QFs at 100 kW or less through
a competitive solicitation.
441. The Commission clarifies that
any competitive solicitation conducted
may not force alteration of existing QF
contracts. A QF receiving a capacity
payment is entitled to that payment for
the duration of the term of its contract,
and a competitive solicitation is
necessarily forward looking based on
the results of that auction.
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
C. Relief From Purchase Obligation in
Competitive Retail Markets
1. NOPR Proposal
442. The Commission in the NOPR
proposed to add regulatory text at the
end of § 292.303(a) of the PURPA
Regulations to provide that a utility’s
purchase obligation may be reduced to
the extent the purchasing electric
utility’s supply obligation has been
reduced by a state retail choice program.
The Commission stated that it was
reasonable for electric utilities’ PURPA
capacity purchase obligations to be
reduced to the extent retail choice
reduces their supply obligations. To the
extent Provider of Last Resort (POLR)
supplies are obtained through
solicitations having a particular contract
term such as one year, the Commission
697 See
18 CFR 292.304(c).
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
proposed that the length of the utility’s
PURPA purchase contract should match
the term of the POLR supply solicitation
contracts in order to more accurately
reflect the utility’s avoided costs.
443. The Commission proposed,
through this change, to provide that
state regulatory authorities and
nonregulated electric utilities have
flexibility to respond to the possibility
that, over time, a utility’s POLR supply
obligation may decrease (or increase).
The Commission intended that this
proposal would apply prospectively
from the effective date of a final rule
and would not disturb contracts in
effect at the time the utility’s supply
obligation is reduced.
2. Comments
444. APPA, DTE Electric, EEI,
Institute for Energy Research,
NorthWestern, NRECA, Pennsylvania
Commission, Portland General, and We
Stand for Energy filed comments in
support of the Commission’s proposal to
provide that the purchase obligation
may be reduced to the extent the
purchasing electric utility’s supply
obligation has been reduced by a state
retail choice program.698
445. New England Small Hydro,
NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA, and
Public Interest Organizations filed
opposing comments arguing that the
Commission lacks the statutory
authority to implement this proposal
because the Commission lacks
discretion to reduce an electric utility’s
mandatory purchase obligation except
through PURPA section 210(m).699 New
England Small Hydro claims that
PURPA section 210(a) clearly states that
electric utilities must purchase the
electric energy from QFs, and that the
Commission does not have the authority
to deviate from the statute.700 NIPPC,
CREA, REC, and OSEIA argues that the
Commission’s existing regulations
adequately address the concern at issue
because any reduction in the long-term
capacity needs of the utility due to retail
access should be reflected in avoided
capacity rates offered to QFs.701 Public
Interest Organizations claim that the
698 APPA Comments at 20; DTE Electric
Comments at 4–5; EEI Comments at 41–42; Institute
for Energy Research Comments at 1–2;
NorthWestern Comments at 8; NRECA Comments at
13–14; Pennsylvania Commission Comments at 6–
7; Portland General Comments at 12–13; and We
Stand Comments at 1.
699 New England Small Hydro Comments at 15–
16; NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at
68–69; and Public Interest Organizations Comments
at 74–75.
700 New England Small Hydro at 16 (citing
Chevron U.S.A., Inc. v. Nat. Res. Def. Council, 467
U.S. 837 (1984)).
701 NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at
69.
PO 00000
Frm 00057
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
54693
Commission proposes to remove state
authority by requiring QF contracts with
a POLR to match the term of the POLR’s
other supply contracts.702 Public
Interest Organizations also state that
even if the Commission had such
authority, there is no evidence in the
record to support matching QF contract
lengths with a POLR’s other supply
contracts. Public Interest Organizations
also assert that the Commission’s
proposal unlawfully discriminates
against QFs to the extent that it fails to
treat QF contracts in parity with any of
a POLR’s other supply contracts.703
446. Biogas and Covanta argue that
the rationale for this proposal is unclear
and that the NOPR fails to justify the
reduction of a utility’s obligation to
purchase QF power based on the
amount of any non-utility generator’s
supply into the utility’s service
territory.704 Covanta states that the
NOPR incorrectly concludes that all
public power is renewable power.705
Biogas and Covanta assert that the
existence of a competitive retail market
does not mean there is a competitive
retail market for biogas or waste-toenergy QFs.706 Biogas and Covanta also
argue that the NOPR would reduce that
already limited market by providing
greater leverage to the purchasing
electric utility, and urge the
Commission to remove barriers to local
government options for energy purchase
rates.
447. Ohio Commission Energy
Advocate states that under Ohio law, an
electric distribution utility is required to
provide consumers within its certified
territory a standard service offer of all
competitive retail electric services
necessary to maintain essential electric
services to customers, including a firm
supply of electric generation services.707
Ohio Commission Energy Advocate
claims that all PUCO-regulated electric
distribution utilities satisfy this
obligation through competitive
solicitation for default service within
the context of an electric security
plan.708 Ohio Commission Energy
Advocate believes that the electric
distribution utility should retain the full
purchase obligation because the
regulated utility maintains the
obligation to serve as the POLR for all
702 Public
Interest Organizations Comments at 74.
at 75.
704 Biogas Comments at 2; Covanta Comments at
703 Id.
9.
705 Covanta
706 Biogas
Comments at 9.
Comments at 2; Covanta Comments at
9–10.
707 Ohio Commission Energy Advocate Comments
at 5.
708 Id. at 6.
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
54694
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
‘‘wires-connected’’ customers.709 Ohio
Commission Energy Advocate also
states that it is concerned by the lack of
alternatives to the mandatory purchase
obligation and would question any
interpretation of PURPA that
contemplates a scenario where no entity
has a purchase obligation for a QF.710
448. ELCON, California Utilities,
Chamber of Commerce, Connecticut
Authority, and Michigan Commission
request further clarification on how the
Commission’s proposal will be
implemented. ELCON states that
industrial customers conditionally
support the reduction in obligation to
purchase based on a state retail choice
program, subject to the development of
clear and enforceable criteria that
exclude mandatory purchase obligation
relief for default supply obligations that
utilities meet with their own
generation.711
Similarly, California Utilities state
that because of the various ways states
have developed restructured retail
markets, the Commission should
provide additional guidance as to the
various ways that state commissions can
address load reductions due to retail
choice while protecting legacy
utilities.712 California Utilities explain
that they need Commission guidance to
ensure that cost recovery for past and
future mandated QF purchases is
equitable to the remaining retail
customers in the legacy utilities’
distribution service areas and that future
PURPA mandates or costs are fairly
allocated consistent with cost-causation
principles.713 Chamber of Commerce
states that the Commission should
clarify that the reduction in a utility’s
QF purchase obligation is measured
against the amount of a utility’s load
that has elected an alternative supplier,
as opposed to eligible load.714 Chamber
of Commerce claims that in certain
states, only a portion of an electric
utility’s load is eligible to select an
alternative electricity supplier and that
such percentage would serve as the
limit for any corresponding reduction in
a utility’s QF purchase obligation.
Michigan Commission states that its
retail choice program caps retail choice
at 10 percent of an electric utility’s retail
customer demand, and seeks
clarification on (1) whether the
reduction in a utility’s purchase
obligation would equal the reduction in
its supply obligation, be based on the
709 Id.
at 6–7.
percentage of its customer demand
participating in the state’s retail choice
program, or some other metric; and (2)
how fluctuations in the state’s retail
choice program and resulting purchase
obligation should be addressed.715
449. Connecticut Authority supports
the proposal to modify distribution
utilities’ must-purchase obligations.716
Connecticut Authority states that since
Connecticut’s electric industry
restructuring, distribution utilities’
purchases of QF output have not been
used to serve retail customers, rather the
distribution utility acts as an
intermediary selling output into the
New England markets. Connecticut
Authority asserts that the Commission
should clarify that the state regulatory
authority is responsible for determining
the appropriate adjustment to the
distribution utility’s must-purchase
obligation and providing notice of such
determination to the Commission.717
450. Connecticut Authority claims
that QF output is different from, and
cannot be substituted in for, distribution
utility-provided default standard or last
resort services. Connecticut Authority
explains that standard service is
procured in six-month tranches, last
resort service is procured in threemonth tranches, and that distribution
utilities do not self-manage their default
service supply portfolios.718
451. Connecticut Authority states that
while it agrees that matching the
contract terms for default service supply
and QF supply could potentially reduce
the burden of over-estimated avoided
costs and give states flexibility to
respond quickly to changes to a
distribution utility’s default supply
obligation, the Commission should not
mandate any term length for the
mandatory purchase obligation.719
Instead, Connecticut Authority asserts
that the Commission should allow the
state to establish the term based on
state-specific circumstances.
452. California Utilities request that
the Commission reaffirm that all
alternative retail suppliers, including
Electric Service Providers (ESP) and
Community Choice Aggregators (CCA),
are electric utilities subject to the
PURPA purchase obligation.720
California Utilities explain that ESPs
and CCAs are the two types of entities
that California allows to sell power to
retail customers in the distribution
service territories of CPUC-regulated
715 Michigan
Commission Comments at 5–6.
Authority Comments at 16.
utilities, and argues that such entities
meet the definition of electric utility
used in PURPA.721
453. California Utilities state that the
Commission should clarify that a state
has no authority to exempt any
traditional or alternative retail supplier
from the PURPA mandatory purchase
obligation in order to ensure QFs that
there is a robust market to sell their
energy and capacity to entities that
actually serve load in the event a legacy
utility is relieved of all or part of its
PURPA obligations.722 California
Utilities also state that the Commission
should clarify that alternative retail
suppliers must make avoided cost
information publicly available to allow
QFs to locate and identify potential
buyers that may have higher avoided
costs than legacy utilities that have lost
load and may no longer have capacity
needs.
454. California Utilities argue that for
states such as California that allow
alternative retail suppliers to opt out of
procuring capacity and require legacy
utilities to provide capacity on their
behalf, it would be unfair for legacy
utilities to pay a QF any amount for
energy greater than the LMP unless the
price differential for which the legacy
utility can sell the energy in the market
is paid for by the alternative retail
supplier that was short on capacity.723
California Utilities explain that this
would prevent cost shifts to customers
who remain with the legacy utility such
that all costs associated with the
mandatory PURPA purchases made by
the legacy utility on behalf of the
alternative retail supplier would be
borne by customers of the alternative
retail supplier.724 California Utilities
also argue that the Commission should
clarify that if legacy utilities are
required to procure capacity from QFs
on behalf of alternative retail suppliers,
states must require alternative retail
suppliers to pay for such QF purchases
at the avoided cost rate set by the state
for the legacy utility for capacity.
455. California Utilities urge the
Commission to adopt a stranded cost
regulation addressing PURPA
obligations incurred by legacy utilities
that lose load to retail competition
consistent with the cost recovery
guarantee in PURPA section
210(m)(7)(A).725 California Utilities
argue that such regulation should be
clear that prudently incurred costs
include any costs associated with a
710 Id.
716 Connecticut
721 Id.
711 ELCON
717 Id.
722 Id.
Comments at 19.
712 California Utilities Comments at 5.
713 Id. at 7.
714 Chamber of Commerce Comments at 5.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
at 17.
718 Id.
719 Id.
at 18.
720 California
PO 00000
Frm 00058
Utilities at 9.
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
at 9–10.
at 11.
723 Id. at 12.
724 Id. at 13.
725 Id. at 14.
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
purchase under a state-mandated
contract. California Utilities propose
new language to § 292.304(g) regarding
implementation of the cost recovery
mandate in section 210(m)(7)(A) of
PURPA stating, in part, that ‘‘[a] state
commission may not find any costs
associated with any legally enforceable
obligation that it has imposed on an
electric utility imprudent.’’ 726
3. Commission Determination
456. In this final rule, we decline to
adopt the proposed regulation
permitting states with retail competition
to allow relief from the purchase
obligation. We instead clarify that the
Commission’s existing PURPA
Regulations already require that states,
to the extent practicable, must account
for reduced loads in setting QF rates.
457. Specifically, 18 CFR
292.304(e)(3) already does and will
continue to allow states, when setting
avoided cost rates, to take into account
‘‘the ability of the electric utility to
avoid costs, including the deferral of
capacity additions.’’ We regard this
existing regulation as allowing a state to
consider reductions in a purchasing
electric utility’s supply obligations
given retail competition and the
purchasing electric utility’s POLR
obligations under state law. We further
clarify that this clarification is not
intended to be reflected as a MW-forMW reduction (or increase) based on
yearly changes in load and therefore
does not and may not serve to terminate
a purchasing utility’s mandatory
purchase obligation under PURPA
section 210(a).727
D. Evaluation of Whether QFs Are at
Separate Sites
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
1. Rebuttable Presumption of Separate
Sites
a. NOPR Proposal
458. The Commission proposed to
allow entities challenging a QF
certification to rebut the presumption
that affiliated facilities located more
than one mile apart are considered to be
separate QFs. The Commission
proposed that this change would be
effective as of the date of the final rule,
which means that such challenges could
only be made to QF certifications and
recertifications that are submitted after
the effective date of the final rule in this
proceeding.
459. The Commission proposed that
an entity can seek to rebut the
presumption only for those facilities
that are located more than one mile
726 Id.
727 18
at 15.
CFR 292.304(e)(3).
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
apart and less than 10 miles apart. The
Commission believed that, just as there
are some facilities that may be so close
that it is reasonable to irrebuttably treat
them as a single facility (those a mile or
less apart), so there are some facilities
that are sufficiently far apart that it is
reasonable to treat them as irrebuttably
separate facilities.728 That latter
distance, the Commission believed, is
10 miles or more apart. Thus, if two
affiliated facilities are one mile or less
apart, they would continue to be
irrebuttably presumed to be a single
facility at a single site. If affiliated
facilities are 10 miles or more apart,
they would be irrebuttably presumed to
be separate facilities at separate sites.
460. The Commission proposed that if
affiliated facilities are more than one
mile apart and less than 10 miles apart,
there would still be a presumption, but
it would be a rebuttable presumption,
that they are separate facilities at
separate sites. Purchasing electric
utilities and others thus would be able
to file a protest attempting to rebut the
presumption for facilities more than one
mile apart and less than 10 miles apart
and argue that they should be treated as
a single facility. The Commission could
also act sua sponte. The Commission
proposed that self-certifications will
remain effective after a protest has been
filed, until such time as the Commission
issues an order revoking the
certification.
461. The Commission proposed
allowing an entity seeking QF status to
provide further information in its
certification (both self-certification and
application for Commission
certification), to preemptively defend
against rebuttal by asserting factors that
affirmatively show that the affiliated
facilities are indeed separate facilities at
separate sites.729 Anyone challenging
the QF certification would be allowed to
assert factors to show that the facilities
are actually part of the same, single
facility.
462. The Commission proposed
limiting protests challenging QF status
by requiring any entity filing a protest
to specify facts that make a prima facie
728 NOPR, 168 FERC ¶ 61,184 at P 101. As
discussed in detail in section IV.D.1.d below, this
final rule will change the references to ‘‘separate
facilities’’ or ‘‘the same facility’’ to ‘‘at separate
sites’’ or ‘‘at the same site.’’
729 While a QF with a net power production
capacity of 1 MW or less is not required to formally
certify its QF status (either through a selfcertification or application for Commission
certification), if the QF’s status is later challenged
(i.e., by a petition for declaratory order), the QF
would be able to respond by affirmatively
demonstrating that its facilities are not located at
the same site as other affiliated facilities and thus
that the QF does not exceed the 80 MW size
limitation.
PO 00000
Frm 00059
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
54695
demonstration that the facility described
in the self-certification, selfrecertification, or Commission
certification does not satisfy the
requirements for QF status. General
allegations or unsupported assertions
would not be a basis for denial of
certification. The Commission further
proposed limiting protests to QF status
by requiring that once the Commission
has affirmatively certified an applicant’s
QF status through either a Commission
certification proceeding or in response
to protests challenging QF status, any
later protest to a QF’s existing
certification asserting that facilities
further than one mile apart are part of
a single QF must demonstrate changed
circumstances that call into question the
continued validity of the earlier
certification.
463. The Commission proposed that
physical and ownership factors may be
asserted to rebut or defend against
rebuttal. Noting that no single factor
would be dispositive, the Commission
proposed the following factors: (1)
Physical characteristics including such
common characteristics as:
infrastructure, property ownership,
interconnection agreements, control
facilities, access and easements,
interconnection facilities up to the point
of interconnection to the distribution or
transmission system, collector systems
or facilities, points of interconnection,
motive force or fuel source, off-take
arrangements, property leases, and
connections to the electrical grid; and
(2) ownership/other characteristics,
including such characteristics as
whether the facilities in question are:
Owned or controlled by the same
person(s) or affiliated persons(s),
operated and maintained by the same or
affiliated entity(ies), selling to the same
electric utility, using common debt or
equity financing, constructed by the
same entity within 12 months,
managing a power sales agreement
executed within 12 months of a similar
and affiliated facility in the same
location, placed into service within 12
months of an affiliated project’s
commercial operation date as specified
in the power sales agreement, or sharing
engineering or procurement contracts.
The Commission solicited comments on
whether the Commission should rely on
some or any of these factors, or other
factors, or whether the various factors
should be considered together and
weighed.
464. The Commission stated that it
will continue to rely on its definition of
‘‘affiliate’’ provided in 18 CFR
35.36(a)(9), and noted that subsection
(iii) provides that the Commission may
determine, after appropriate notice and
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
54696
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
opportunity for hearing, that a person
stands in such relation to a specified
company that there is likely to be an
absence of arm’s-length bargaining in
transactions between them as to make it
necessary or appropriate in the public
interest or for the protection of investors
or consumers that the person be treated
as an affiliate.730 The Commission
intended, when applying its rules on
separate facilities, to consider this
provision of its regulations, when
entities otherwise would not be deemed
affiliates under the other provisions of
the definition, to determine whether a
person nevertheless should be treated as
an affiliate. In doing so, the Commission
stated that it could take into
consideration many of the same factors
that would reasonably be considered in
evaluating whether facilities located
over one and less than 10 miles apart
are a single facility or separate facilities.
465. The Commission believed that
this change, together with the proposed
definition of ‘‘electrical generating
equipment’’ and revision to the FERC
Form No. 556, would more closely align
with Congress’s requirement that QFs
seeking to certify as small power
production facilities are in fact below
the 80 MW statutory limit for such
facilities.731
b. Commission Determination
466. As further discussed and revised
in the following sections, we adopt the
NOPR proposal. Henceforth, if a small
power production facility seeking QF
status is located one mile or less from
any affiliated small power production
QFs that use the same energy resource,
it will be irrebuttably presumed to be at
the same site as those affiliated small
power production QFs. If a small power
production facility seeking QF status is
located ten miles or more from any
affiliated small power production QFs
that use the same energy resource, it
will be irrebuttably presumed to be at a
separate site from those affiliated small
power production QFs. If a small power
production facility seeking QF status is
located more than one mile but less than
ten miles from any affiliated small
power production QFs that use the same
energy resource, it will be rebuttably
presumed to be at a separate site from
those affiliated small power production
QFs.
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
730 18
CFR 35.36(a)(9)(iii).
16 U.S.C. 796(17)(A)(ii) (defining small
power production facility as, inter alia, ‘‘a facility
which is an eligible solar, wind, waste, or
geothermal facility, or a facility which—. . . has a
power production capacity which, together with
any other facilities located at the same site (as
determined by the Commission), is not greater than
80 megawatts’’).
731 See
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
467. We adopt the proposal to allow
a small power production facility
seeking QF status to provide further
information in its certification (both
self-certification and application for
Commission certification) or
recertification (both self-certification
and application for Commission
recertification), to preemptively defend
against anticipated challenges by
identifying factors that affirmatively
show that its facility is indeed at a
separate site from affiliated small power
production QFs that use the same
energy resource and that are more than
one but less than 10 miles from its
facility. We will correspondingly allow
any interested person or entity to
challenge a QF certification (both selfcertification and application for
Commission certification) or
recertification (both self-recertification
or application for Commission
recertification) that makes substantive
changes to the existing certification as
further described below).732
468. As explained in section IV.D.1.f
below, we adopt the NOPR’s proposed
factors, with certain additions.
469. We adopt the proposal to clarify
that challenges to QF status require that
the interested person or entity filing a
protest must specify facts that make a
prima facie demonstration that the
facility described in the certification
(both self-certification and application
for Commission certification) or
recertification (both self-recertification
and application for Commission
recertification) does not satisfy the
requirements for QF status.
Additionally, any protest must be
adequately supported, with supporting
documents, contracts, or affidavits, as
appropriate. General allegations or
unsupported assertions will not provide
a basis for denial of certification or
recertification. We additionally limit
protests, as described more fully in
section IV.E below, by clarifying that
protests may be made to an initial
certification (both self-certification and
application for Commission
certification) filed on or after the
effective date of this final rule, but only
to a recertification (both selfrecertification and application for
Commission recertification) filed on or
after the effective date of this final rule
that makes substantive changes to the
existing certification. We adopt the
proposal to limit protests by requiring
that once the Commission has
affirmatively certified an applicant’s QF
732 We note that a protester must separately file
for intervention seeking to be made a party to the
proceeding; the filing of a protest does not make
that person or entity a party. 18 CFR 385.102(c),
385.211(a)(2).
PO 00000
Frm 00060
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
status in response to a protest opposing
a self-certification or self-recertification,
or in response to an application for
Commission certification or
recertification, any later protest to a
recertification (self-recertification or
application for Commission
recertification) making substantive
changes to a QF’s existing certification
must demonstrate changed
circumstances from the facts on which
the Commission acted on the
certification filing that call into question
the continued validity of the earlier
certification.733 Finally, the Commission
retains the discretion to summarily
reject protests where a protest reiterates
arguments already made against the
same QF that the Commission
previously denied or otherwise rejected.
c. Need for Reform
i. Comments
470. Multiple parties have expressed
concern that some QF developers of
small power production facilities are
circumventing the one-mile rule, and
thereby circumventing PURPA, by
strategically siting small power
production facilities that use the same
energy resource slightly more than one
mile apart in order to qualify as separate
small power production facilities.734
Several commenters state that the
NOPR-proposed changes will reduce the
opportunity for gaming.735
471. Several commenters argue, to the
contrary, that there is no evidence of
733 An interested person or entity can choose to
file a petition for declaratory order, with fee, at any
time (that is, not only within 30 days from the date
of the filing of the Form No. 556). However, if the
Commission has affirmatively certified an
applicant’s QF status in response to a protest
opposing a self-certification or self-recertification,
or in response to an application for Commission
certification or recertification, any later petition for
declaratory order protesting the QFs existing
certification must demonstrate changed
circumstances from the time the Commission acted
on the certification that call into question the
continued validity of the earlier certification.
734 See APPA Comments at 21; Center for Growth
and Opportunity Comments at 5–6; Consumers
Energy Comments at 4; East River Comments at 1–
2; EEI Comments at 43; ELCON Comments at 35;
Governor of Idaho Comments at 1; Idaho
Commission Comments at 5–7; Idaho Power
Comments at 13; Missouri River Energy Comments
at 5; Mr. Moore Comments at 2; Northern Laramie
Range Alliance Comments at 2; NorthWestern
Comments at 9; NRECA Comments at 14–15;
Portland General Comments at 14.
735 APPA Comments at 21; Center for Growth and
Opportunity Comments at 5–6; Consumers Energy
Comments at 4; East River Comments at 1–2; EEI
Comments at 43; ELCON Comments at 35; Governor
of Idaho Comments at 1; Idaho Commission
Comments at 5–7; Idaho Power Comments at 13;
Missouri River Energy Comments at 5; Mr. Moore
Comments at 2; Northern Laramie Range Alliance
Comments at 2; NorthWestern Comments at 12;
NRECA Comments at 14–15; Portland General
Comments at 14.
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
gaming of the current one-mile rule.736
Con Edison argues that utilities are not
overwhelmed with QFs using the onemile rule and there is little to no
evidence to the contrary.737 sPower
states that it is difficult to see how
developers that comply with this clear
bright-line rule could be said to be
circumventing.738 New England Small
Hydro argues that the Commission is
attempting to address perceived abuses
of the 80 MW limitation by burdening
projects that do not abuse the system.739
ii. Commission Determination
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
472. The record shows that, since the
establishment of the one-mile rule in the
PURPA Regulations in 1980, the
development of large numbers of
affiliated renewable resource facilities,
requires a revision of the one mile-rule.
We find that the final rule will reduce
the opportunity for developers of small
power production facilities to
circumvent the current one-mile rule by
strategically siting small power
production facilities that use the same
energy resource slightly more than one
mile apart.740 While such
circumvention may not be an everyday
occurrence, we agree with commenters
that the record demonstrates it is still a
sufficient possibility under the current
regulations that the Commission is
justified in addressing it in order to
comply with the statute.741 The final
rule, as adopted, still retains the
presumption that small power
production QFs more than one mile
apart are located at separate sites, but
simply makes the presumption
rebuttable for small power production
QFs located more than one mile but less
than 10 miles apart, allowing the
Commission the ability to address those
circumstances.
736 Solar Energy Industries Comments at 51;
Southeast Public Interest Organizations Comments
at 31; SC Solar Alliance Comments at 19.
737 Con Edison Comments at 5.
738 sPower Comments at 5.
739 New England Small Hydro Comments at 17.
740 The regulation, in practice, is only of
consequence if the facilities located ‘‘at the same
site’’ would exceed a power production capacity of
80 MW, as that is the size limit for a small power
production facility to qualify as a QF. 16 U.S.C.
796(17)(A)(ii).
741 See APPA Comments at 21; Center for Growth
and Opportunity Comments at 5–6; Consumers
Energy Comments at 4; East River Comments at 1–
2; EEI Comments at 43; ELCON Comments at 35;
Governor of Idaho Comments at 1; Idaho
Commission Comments at 5–7; Idaho Power
Comments at 13; Missouri River Energy Comments
at 5; Mr. Moore Comments at 2; Northern Laramie
Range Alliance Comments at 2; NorthWestern
Comments at 9; NRECA Comments at 14–15;
Portland General Comments at 14.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
54697
site.’’ In that regard, we change
references to ‘‘separate facilities’’ or
i. Comments
‘‘the same facility’’ to ‘‘at separate sites’’
473. Solar Energy Industries state that, or ‘‘at the same site.’’
in El Dorado County Water Agency, the
477. The NOPR refers to determining
Commission found that ‘‘the critical test
whether
affiliated facilities are ‘‘separate
under PURPA relates to whether the
facilities’’ or ‘‘a single facility.’’
facilities are located at one site rather
However, both the statute and the
than whether they are integrated as a
existing regulations contemplate that
project.’’ 742 Solar Energy Industries
argue that the proposed rule, as drafted, the Commission will determine what is
‘‘the same site,’’ 749 and do not require
abandons the focus on whether the
the
Commission to determine whether
facilities are located at one site and
two facilities are a single facility. The
transforms it into an analysis as to
statute defines a small power
whether affiliated QFs are part of the
production facility as an eligible facility,
same project. Solar Energy Industries
similarly contend that it is arbitrary to
which, together with other facilities
change from a ‘‘same site’’ to an
located at the same site (as determined
‘‘integrated project’’ standard.743
by the Commission), has a power
474. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA
production capacity no greater than 80
state that the existing rule is a
MW,750 and the Commission’s
reasonable means of implementing the
regulations have long approached the
statutory phrase ‘‘same site,’’
matter as defining how to determine
particularly given the statutory directive ‘‘the same site.’’ 751 We find that the
to encourage QF development, and state Commission’s determination of whether
that they prefer the current bright line
or not a small power production facility
rule.744 Allco argues that the proposed
is a QF (i.e., exceeds a power production
rule is divorced from the statutory use
capacity of 80 MW) should continue to
of ‘‘site.’’ Allco asserts that the
be focused on whether the small power
Commission lacks authority to define
production facility seeking QF status
the term ‘‘site’’ in a manner other than
and other nearby affiliated small power
one reasonably related to its ordinary
production QFs are at the same site or
meaning and argues that the
at separate sites.
Commission’s definition of site
478. We also modify the NOPR
arbitrarily limits QF development for no
apparent reason.745 The DC Commission proposal to change the irrebuttable and
would like the Commission to leave the rebuttable presumptions regarding
affiliated facilities to instead apply to
resolution of certain disputes over
affiliated small power production
whether QFs are separate to state
commissions.746 Idaho also requests that qualifying facilities. As noted, the NOPR
refers to determining whether affiliated
states be given as much discretion as
facilities are ‘‘separate facilities’’ or ‘‘a
possible.747
475. EEI states that the interpretation
single facility.’’ We find that only
of ‘‘same site’’ is determined by the
affiliated small power production QFs
Commission, and that there is nothing
are relevant to the determination of
in the statute that prevents the
whether the small power production
Commission from modifying its
facility seeking QF status and other
interpretation of the term ‘‘same
nearby facilities are at the same site or
site.’’ 748
separate sites.752 Correspondingly, as
further
detailed below, we will allow
ii. Commission Determination
entities challenging a QF certification
476. We modify the NOPR proposal to (both self-certification and application
change terminology relating to the
for Commission certification) or
determination of whether small power
recertification (both self-recertification
production facilities are separate
and application for Commission
facilities to focus not on whether they
recertification) to rebut the presumption
are separate facilities, but rather to
that a small power production facility
mirror the statutory language and thus
seeking QF status is at a separate site
focus on whether they are at ‘‘the same
from any affiliated small power
production QFs that use the same
742 Solar Energy Industries Comments at 60
energy resource and that are located
(quoting El Dorado Cty. Water Agency, 24 FERC
d. Site Definition
¶ 61,280, at 61,578 (1983)).
743 Id. at 61–62.
744 NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at
70.
745 Allco Comments at 16.
746 DC Commission Comments at 9.
747 Idaho Comments at 1.
748 EEI Comments at 42.
PO 00000
Frm 00061
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
749 16
U.S.C. 796(17)(A)(i); 18 CFR 292.204(a).
U.S.C. 796(17)(A)(i).
751 18 CFR 292.204(a).
752 We note, however, that, in the context of a
PURPA section 210(m) proceeding, all affiliates are
relevant in evaluating whether a QF has
nondiscriminatory access to a competitive market.
750 16
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
54698
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
more than one but less than 10 miles
from it.753
479. We therefore modify the
language proposed in the NOPR. In sum,
we find that if a small power production
facility seeking QF status is located one
mile or less from any affiliated small
power production QFs that use the same
energy resource, it will be irrebuttably
presumed to be ‘‘at the same site’’ as
those affiliated small power production
QFs (rather than a single facility at a
single site, as proposed in the NOPR).
The Commission finds that if a small
power production facility seeking QF
status is located ten miles or more from
any affiliated small power production
QFs that use the same energy resource,
it will be irrebuttably presumed to be at
a separate site from those affiliated
small power production QFs (rather
than separate facilities at separate sites,
as proposed by the NOPR). We find that
if a small power production facility
seeking QF status is located more than
one but less than ten miles from any
affiliated small power production QFs
that use the same energy resource, it
will be rebuttably presumed to be at a
separate site from those affiliated small
power production QFs (rather than
separate facilities at separate sites, as
proposed in the NOPR).
480. Purchasing electric utilities and
others will be able to file a protest and
identify factors attempting to rebut the
presumption for a small power
production facility seeking QF status
that has an affiliated small power
production QF that uses the same
energy resource more than one but less
than 10 miles from it, and argue that the
small power production facility seeking
QFs status should be treated as ‘‘at the
same site’’ as the affiliated small power
production QF located more than one
but less than 10 miles from it (rather
than as a single facility, as proposed in
the NOPR). We will allow a small power
production facility seeking QF status to
provide further information in its
certification (both self-certification and
application for Commission
certification) or recertification (both
self-recertification and application for
Commission recertification) to
preemptively defend against rebuttal by
identifying factors that affirmatively
show that its facility is indeed at a
separate site from an affiliated small
power production QF located more than
one but less than 10 miles from it (rather
than separate facilities at separate sites,
as proposed in the NOPR).
753 Though not at issue here, we also note that the
facilities need to use the same energy resource. 18
CFR 292.204(a)(1).
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
481. Regarding the requests to allow
states to decide whether affiliated small
power production QFs are located at
separate sites, we note that, in PURPA
section 201, now codified in section 3
(17) of the FPA, Congress authorized the
Commission to determine whether the
applicant and other facilities are located
at the same site. This Commission will
therefore continue to make these
determinations.
e. Distance Between Facilities
i. Comments
482. Several commenters contend that
the proposal to institute a rebuttable
presumption for facilities that are more
than one mile but less than 10 miles
apart is arbitrary and lacks sufficient
supporting evidence.754 ELCON notes
that the choice of 10 miles as the
threshold is not supported by any
evidence.755
483. Regarding the proposed
rebuttable presumption for QFs more
than one but less than 10 miles apart,
Terna Energy argues that the NOPR
effectively increases the ‘‘exclusion
zone’’ around a QF’s electrical
generating equipment from
approximately three square miles
(3.1415 square miles, the circle with
one-mile radius around the QF’s
electrical generating equipment,
assuming a point generating source) to
over 300 square miles (i.e. a 10-mile
radius circle), a 100-times increase to
the ‘‘exclusion area’’ for a single QF.756
484. New England Small Hydro notes
that hydroelectric generators are located
where river conditions are ideal for
generating and that, while they are not
generally located within one mile, there
may be some projects owned by
affiliates that are within 10 miles of
each other.757
485. Borrego Solar opposes applying
the proposed changes to the one-mile
rule to distributed generation and finds
that it would restrict the ability of
developers to follow market signals
when locating projects and significantly
increase the regulatory burden. Borrego
Solar notes that there are several reasons
that otherwise different projects from
the same company would be within 10
miles of each other, including land
zoning restrictions, available substation
capacity, and optimal topology or
insolation.758 Borrego Solar notes that it
754 Allco Comments at 16; Ares Comments at 7;
Borrego Solar Comments at 4; ELCON Comments at
19; Public Interest Organizations Comments at 93;
SC Solar Alliance Comments at 17; Solar Energy
Industries Comments at 60, 62.
755 ELCON Comments at 35–36.
756 Terna Energy Comments at 4.
757 New England Small Hydro Comments at 17.
758 Borrego Solar Comments at 3–4.
PO 00000
Frm 00062
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
is common for projects on the
distribution system to be within two
miles of a substation or three-phase
lines to reduce interconnection costs.
Borrego Solar states that it is also
common for multiple unaffiliated
developers to site their projects in a
single area within just a few miles of
each other, and later sell those projects
to a single entity much later in the
process, inadvertently violating the
Commission’s rules.759 Borrego Solar
would like the Commission to exclude
projects directly interconnected to the
distribution system or initially
developed by different entities from any
presumption of common development.
Borrego Solar urges the Commission to,
at a minimum, establish a streamlined,
low-cost option for challenging any
presumption of common development,
to avoid casting a chill over project
development and driving developers
and long-term owners out of the market
due to the risks of having the projects
disqualified.760
486. North Carolina DOJ argues that
the proposed rule, by discouraging
facilities from being placed close to one
another, also runs counter to a North
Carolina policy based on efficient use of
electric resources.761 North Carolina
DOJ and North Carolina Commission
Staff state that the rules in North
Carolina incentivize the installation of
production facilities close to substations
so projects naturally appear in clusters
surrounding transmission and
distribution infrastructure.762 North
Carolina DOJ says that the proposed rule
fails to take into account the complex
and regionally specific factors driving
the siting, financing, operation, and
maintenance of production facilities.763
487. Industrial Energy Consumers
state that the NOPR does not distinguish
between merchant small power
production QFs built to sell electricity
to third parties and self-supply QFs
built primarily to support
manufacturing or industrial processes.
Industrial Energy Consumers state that
there are many manufacturing company
sites that are of a 10-mile length.
Industrial Energy Consumers state that
the Commission’s proposed changes to
the one-mile rule should be clarified to
exclude ‘‘self-supply’’ QFs.764
488. Solar Energy Industries believes
that for facilities less than one mile
759 Id.
at 4.
at 5.
761 North Carolina DOJ Comments at 8.
762 Id.; North Carolina Commission Staff
Comments at 6.
763 North Carolina DOJ Comments at 6.
764 Industrial Energy Consumers Comments at 16.
760 Id.
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
apart the Commission should continue
to waive the rule where appropriate.765
489. Regarding the proposed
irrebuttable presumption that facilities
located more than 10 miles apart are
separate facilities, NorthWestern urges
the Commission to consider increasing
the distance. NorthWestern explains
that its operations in Montana are
geographically very expansive and 10
miles in Montana is not a substantial
distance, especially when compared to
other states that are geographically
much smaller. NorthWestern states that
Montana’s electric system has more than
24,450 miles of electric transmission
and distribution lines to serve
approximately 374,000 customers, and
that its electric operations are very rural
and cover more than 97,500 square
miles.766 NorthWestern therefore
recommends that the Commission
consider expanding this distance to
accommodate utilities in the West that
have very large service territories.767
ii. Commission Determination
490. We adopt the NOPR proposal
that an entity can seek to rebut the
presumption of separate sites only for
an entity seeking small power
production QF status with an affiliated
small power production QF or QFs that
are located more than one and less than
10 miles from it.
491. We recognize, as we have
previously for the one-mile rule,768 that
it is debatable as to where exactly these
thresholds are most appropriately set.
PURPA requires that no small power
production facility, together with other
facilities located ‘‘at the same site,’’
exceed 80 MWs, and Congress has
tasked the Commission with defining
what constitutes facilities being at the
same site for purposes of PURPA. We
find that providing set geographic
distances will limit unnecessary
disputes over whether facilities are at
the same site, and therefore must choose
reasonable distances at which small
power production facilities will be
considered irrebuttably at the same site
or irrebuttably at separate sites. There
are some affiliated small power
production facilities using the same
energy resource that are so close
together that it is reasonable to treat
them as irrebuttably at the same site.
The Commission finds that one mile or
less is a reasonable distance to treat
such facilities as irrebuttably at the
same site. Likewise, there are some
765 Solar Energy Industries Comments at 60–61
(citing Windfarms, Ltd., 13 FERC ¶ 61,017, at 61,032
(1980) (Windfarms)).
766 NorthWestern Comments at 10.
767 Id.
768 See Windfarms, 13 FERC at 61,032.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
small power production facilities that
are affiliated and may use the same
energy resource but that are sufficiently
far apart that it is reasonable to treat
them as irrebuttably at separate sites.
The Commission finds that 10 miles or
more is a reasonable distance to treat
such facilities as irrebuttably at separate
sites. For affiliated small power
production facilities using the same
resource that are more than one mile but
less than 10 miles apart, the
Commission finds that the distinction
between same site or separate site is not
as clear, and therefore finds that it is
reasonable to treat them as rebuttably at
separate sites, and to allow interested
parties to provide evidence to attempt to
rebut that presumption. The
Commission finds that establishing
these reasonable distances, and
particularly establishing the ability to
rebut the presumption of separate sites
for affiliated small power production
facilities more than one mile but less
than 10 miles apart, better allows the
Commission to address the evolving
shape and configuration of resources,
such as modular solar or wind power
plants, that are being developed as QFs,
and provides for improved
administration of PURPA. The
Commission therefore finds that the
one-mile and 10-mile limits are
reasonable inflection points for
differentiating between the same site
and separate sites.
492. The Commission understands
that there may be many reasons that
guide developers’ decisions on where to
site facilities, and for siting them near
to (or far from) each other. The
Commission reiterates that for affiliated
small power production QFs that are
more than one and less than 10 miles
apart, there is still a presumption that
they are at separate sites, though the
Commission today makes that
presumption a rebuttable
presumption.769 We also adopt today
the proposal to allow an entity seeking
QF status to provide further information
in its certification (both self-certification
and application for Commission
certification) or recertification (both
self-recertification and application for
Commission recertification) to
preemptively defend against rebuttal by
identifying factors that affirmatively
769 For hydroelectric generating facilities, the
regulations currently provide that the same energy
resources essentially means ‘‘the same
impoundment for power generation,’’ see 18 CFR
292.204(a)(2)(i), and it is unlikely that hydroelectric
generating facilities located more than a mile apart
would rely on the same impoundment. Should that
circumstance arise, though, the applicant facility
could seek waiver, arguing that the facilities should
not be considered to be at the same site. See 18 CFR
292.204(a)(3).
PO 00000
Frm 00063
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
54699
show that its facility is indeed at a
separate site from affiliated small power
production QFs more than one but less
than 10 miles from it. Additionally, we
note that we are retaining waiver
provision in 18 CFR 292.204(a)(3),
allowing the Commission to waive the
method of calculation of the size of the
facility for good cause.770
493. Borrego Solar raises the concern
that unaffiliated developers may site
their projects within a few miles of each
other, and later sell those projects to a
single entity much later in the process,
inadvertently violating the
Commission’s rules. The Commission
finds that it is reasonable to expect the
single purchasing entity in the example
to be on notice about the size and
locations of its QF acquisitions and the
requirements of both PURPA and the
Commission’s regulations, just as it
would need to consider other regulatory
requirements associated with its
acquisition. Moreover, ownership by a
single entity of multiple small power
production QFs in close proximity to
each other that together exceed a power
production capacity of 80 MW, and
whether this improperly circumvents
the Commission’s regulations, is
precisely what the new rebuttable
presumption is seeking to address.
494. Regarding Industrial Energy
Consumers’ request that the
Commission’s changes be clarified to
exclude ‘‘self-supply’’ QFs, the
Commission declines to do so. PURPA
limits the power production capacity of
a small power production QF, together
with any other facilities located at the
same site (as determined by the
Commission), to 80 MW.771 The
Commission finds that Industrial Energy
Consumer’s argument that ‘‘self-supply’’
QFs are built primarily to support
manufacturing and industrial processes
does not negate the fact that the ‘‘selfsupply’’ QFs in question are small
power production facilities limited to 80
MW. Similarly, its argument also does
not justify different application of the
same site determination. The
Commission will therefore apply the
same site determinations to all small
power production QFs. The
Commission notes that, as with other
small power production QFs, an
individual ‘‘self-supply’’ QF may assert
relevant factors to show why it should
not be considered to be at the same site
as an affiliated small power production
QF that is more than one but less than
10 miles away from it. For example, if
a self-supply facility seeking QF status
was within 10 miles of an affiliated
770 See
771 16
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
18 CFR 292.204(a)(3).
U.S.C. 796(17)(A)(ii).
02SER2
54700
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
small power production QF, but the
energy from each facility was used
primarily to supply different end users,
the self-supply facility seeking QF status
could argue that this fact supports that
it is at a separate site from the affiliated
small power production QF, and the
Commission would consider this fact in
its evaluation.
495. Regarding Terna Energy’s
contention that the new rule causes a
100-times increase to the ‘‘exclusion
zone’’ around a QF’s electrical
generating equipment, we believe that
the rule providing for a rebuttable
presumption for affiliated small power
production QFs located more than one
but less than 10 miles apart, as
promulgated today, is necessary to
address allegations of improper
circumvention of the one-mile rule that
both previously and in comments have
been presented to the Commission.
496. We reject NorthWestern’s request
to increase the distance of the
irrebuttable presumption of separate
sites to more than 10 miles.
Northwestern argues that 10 miles is not
a significant distance compared to the
geographic expansiveness of its system.
We believe this is an irrelevant
comparison; what matters is not how
large or small the purchasing electric
utility’s service territory is or how rural
it may be or how many miles of
transmission lines it may have, but the
question presented by the statute, i.e.,
whether or not the affiliated small
power production QFs are located at the
same site. As described above, we have
decided that 10 miles is a reasonable
and appropriate distance at which to
apply the irrebuttable presumption of
separate sites, irrespective of how
expansive, or diminutive, the
purchasing electric utility’s system may
be.
f. Factors
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
i. Comments
497. Several commenters state that
they support the factors for evaluating
whether or not facilities are at the same
site, which are described in the
NOPR.772 SC Solar Alliance and the
Southeast Public Interest Organizations
support considering a common point of
interconnection or a single real estate
parcel or owner as factors weighing
towards a determination that multiple
projects are a single facility.773
772 APPA Comments at 21–22; Connecticut
Authority Comments at 19–20; Idaho Commission
Comments at 6–7; NARUC Comments at 5; Portland
General Comments at 15.
773 SC Solar Alliance Comments at 17; Southeast
Public Interest Organization Comments at 34.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
498. Several commenters offer
additional factors for consideration.774
North Carolina Commission Staff states
that the Commission should also
consider whether the QF is attempting
to game the system by getting rates for
which they would otherwise be
ineligible, as well as where the facilities
were constructed and when common
ownership commenced.775 Northern
Laramie Range Alliance suggests that
relevant factors could include, for
example, direct or indirect ownership
by the same party or parties,
interconnection at a single substation,
simultaneous site acquisition and/or
state and local permitting.776 Allco
proposes that the criteria to determine if
sites are separate should be whether
they share infrastructure, private roads
or interconnection agreements in
common.777 NRECA proposes that the
types of evidence could include
evidence of contemporaneous
construction, shared interconnection,
common communication and control,
use of the same step-up transformer, and
common permitting and land leasing.778
The Idaho Commission proposes that
relevant factors include whether they
share an interconnection agreement,
obtained local, state or federal permits
under the same application or as the
same entity, and if they have a revenue
sharing agreement.779
Portland General suggests that the
Commission include past ownership of
projects as a factor.780
499. Regarding the relative weight of
the factors, the Southeast Public Interest
Organizations would like the
Commission to identify which factors
would be definitive in a QF being able
to proactively demonstrate that their site
is separate.781 Both Basin and EEI
would like the Commission to clarify
that the list of factors to be considered
is not exhaustive or weighted.782
NorthWestern contends that the
Commission should specify that a
showing of any one factor is sufficient
to rebut the presumption. NorthWestern
argues that the Commission should have
the flexibility to deal with this issue on
a case-by-case basis and expand or
774 Allco Comments at 16; Idaho Commission
Comments at 6–7; North Carolina Commission Staff
Comments at 6; Northern Laramie Range Alliance
Comments at 3; NRECA Comments at 15–16.
775 North Carolina Commission Staff Comments at
6.
776 Northern Laramie Range Alliance Comments
at 3.
777 Allco Comments at 16.
778 NRECA Comments at 15–16.
779 Idaho Commission Comments at 6–7.
780 Portland General Comments at 15.
781 Southeast Public Interest Organization
Comments at 34.
782 Basin Comments at 12; EEI Comments at 45.
PO 00000
Frm 00064
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
modify the list of factors where
appropriate.783
500. NorthWestern states that it has
concerns about the Commission’s
reliance on 18 CFR 35.36(a)(9), because,
according to NorthWestern, developers
carefully structure the ownership of
their companies to ensure that they are
not, technically, legal affiliates when, in
fact, considering the totality of the
circumstances, they are affiliates. For
these reasons, NorthWestern strongly
urges the Commission to consider the
physical characteristic factors identified
for determining the distance between
facilities in order to also determine if
facilities are owned by affiliates.784
NorthWestern states that, for example, if
one facility only owns five percent
voting interest in another facility, but
the two facilities have one
interconnection request and use the
same collector system, the Commission
should be able to find that there are
sufficient facts so that they are treated
as affiliates for purposes of the one-mile
rule.785
501. Several commenters opposed the
Commission’s proposed factors.786 SC
Solar Alliance states that the range of
factors included under the categories of
‘‘ownership/other characteristics’’ and
‘‘physical characteristics’’ is overly
broad and could be subject to
inconsistent or problematic
interpretation. For example, SC Solar
Alliance states that the term
‘‘infrastructure’’ is undefined and
ambiguous, and ‘‘control facilities,’’
‘‘access and easements,’’ ‘‘collector
systems or facilities,’’ and ‘‘property
leases’’ are all vague and imprecise.787
SC Solar Alliance agrees with Solar
Energy Industries’ emphasis that under
no scenario should common financing
be relevant, as unquestionably distinct
facilities are frequently financed as part
of a bundled portfolio.788
502. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA
strongly oppose use of common
interconnection facilities as a factor
because separately owned facilities are
likely to share interconnection facilities
to reduce costs and build off of existing
infrastructure. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and
OSEIA state that, given that there are
only a limited number of qualified
783 NorthWestern
784 Id.
Comments at 11.
at 12.
785 Id.
786 Ares Comments at 5–7; Borrego Solar
Comments at 3–4; NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA
Comments at 73; Solar Energy Industries Comments
at 62; SC Solar Alliance Comments at 16–18;
Southeast Public Interest Organizations Comments
at 34.
787 SC Solar Alliance Comments at 17.
788 Id. at 16 (citing Solar Energy Industries
Supplemental Comments, Docket No. AD16–16, at
55–56 (August 28, 2019)).
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
maintenance providers and other
service contractors, the fact that two
facilities use the same contractors
should not be relevant to common
ownership and control of two facilities.
NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA state
that the fact that two facilities are
constructed within 12 months of each
other could merely be evidence that the
market conditions at the time favored
construction of the facilities, not that
the facilities are intended to be one
facility.789
503. SC Solar Alliance states that the
extensive list of ‘‘ownership/other
characteristics’’ as written is highly
problematic. Control and maintenance,
particularly in North and South
Carolina where there are a substantial
number of distributed solar facilities, is
often contracted for by a limited number
of solar maintenance companies.
Allowing the existence of a common
maintenance company to in any way
dictate QF status is entirely
unreasonable and bears no relationship
to the question at hand.790 Similarly,
other factors included in the NOPR,
including the sale of electricity to a
common utility, a common financing
lender, the use of a mutual contractor
for project construction, the timing of
contract execution, and the timing of
facilities being placed into service do
not provide relevant evidence as to
common ownership requiring facilities
to be considered a single QF. Applying
these factors would create an
unnecessary and undue burden on QFs,
particularly smaller distributionconnected QFs that have been
constructed relatively nearby and which
often rely on a limited number of local
contractors and partners to complete
this necessary work.791
504. The Southeast Public Interest
Organizations are concerned that the
use of common contractors, financing
entity, maintenance companies, or sales
to the same entity and such could be
used against QFs that are built in the
same area but are otherwise separate
sites.792
505. SC Solar Alliance states that the
Commission’s statement that ‘‘no single
factor would be dispositive’’ is
troubling, and that it is inconceivable
that QF ownership would not be
dispositive in any such rebuttable
presumption. SC Solar Alliance states
that it would be wholly unjust and
unreasonable to consider a solar facility
owned by one solar developer to be
considered part of a solar facility owned
by a distinct and unaffiliated solar
developer. SC Solar Alliance states that
any rebuttable presumption should
include ‘‘separate ownership’’ as a
dispositive indication of separate
facilities.793
506. North Carolina DOJ states that
the element of common control is a
challenging question because of the
limited number of companies available
to operate renewable energy facilities.
North Carolina DOJ asserts that a
handful of firms are responsible for the
operation and maintenance work for
close to half of the country’s solar
energy production facilities.794
507. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA
state that the Commission should
include substantially more specific
parameters about what evidence a
project would need to submit to
demonstrate single-project status and
should make clear that this test has no
applicability unless generators within
one to 10 miles are owned by the same
company or affiliates of the same
company. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and
OSEIA assert that ‘‘the decisive factors
are the ‘stream of benefits’ from the
project and control of the venture,’’
which the Commission defined ‘‘to
include entitlement to profits, losses,
and surplus after return of initial capital
contribution.’’ 795 These criteria could
be used to objectively evaluate whether
two QFs within 10 miles are commonly
owned or controlled, as opposed to also
putting two separately owned and
controlled facilities at risk of violating
the rule based solely on physical
characteristics.796
ii. Commission Determination
508. We adopt the physical and
ownership factors proposed in the
NOPR, including as noted above the
ability of a QF to preemptively identify
the factors in its filing in anticipation of
protests to its filing. As explained above
in section IV.D.1.d we are modifying the
NOPR proposal to change terminology
relating to the determination of whether
facilities are separate facilities to focus
not on whether they are separate
facilities, but rather to mirror the
statutory language and thus focus on
whether they are at ‘‘the same site.’’
Accordingly, we adopt these factors as
relevant indicia of whether affiliated
small power production facilities are ‘‘at
793 SC
789 NIPPC,
CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at
73–74.
790 SC Solar Alliance Comments at 17–18.
791 Id.
792 Southeast Public Interest Organizations
Comments at 34.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
Solar Alliance Comments at 17.
Carolina DOJ Comments at 8.
795 NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at
73 (citing CMS Midland, Inc., 50 FERC ¶ 61,098, at
61,278–279 (1990), aff’d Mich. Municipal Coop.
Group v. FERC, 990 F.2d 1377 (D.C. Cir. 1993)).
796 Id.
794 North
PO 00000
Frm 00065
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
54701
the same site.’’ In addition, we modify
the NOPR proposal to identify the
following additional physical factors as
indicia that small power production
facilities should be considered to be
located at the same site: (1) Evidence of
shared control systems; (2) common
permitting and land leasing; and (3)
shared step-up transformers.
509. Specifically, we adopt the factors
listed below as examples of the factors
the Commission may consider in
deciding whether small power
production facilities that are owned by
the same person(s) or its affiliates are
located ‘‘at the same site’’: (1) Physical
characteristics, including such common
characteristics as: Infrastructure,
property ownership, property leases,
control facilities, access and easements,
interconnection agreements,
interconnection facilities up to the point
of interconnection to the distribution or
transmission system, collector systems
or facilities, points of interconnection,
motive force or fuel source, off-take
arrangements, connections to the
electrical grid, evidence of shared
control systems, common permitting
and land leasing, and shared step-up
transformers; and (2) ownership/other
characteristics, including such
characteristics as whether the facilities
in question are: Owned or controlled by
the same person(s) or affiliated
persons(s),797 operated and maintained
by the same or affiliated entity(ies),
selling to the same electric utility, using
common debt or equity financing,
constructed by the same entity within
12 months, managing a power sales
agreement executed within 12 months
of a similar and affiliated small power
production qualifying facility in the
same location, placed into service
within 12 months of an affiliated small
power production QF project’s
commercial operation date as specified
in the power sales agreement, or sharing
engineering or procurement contracts.
510. We adopt the NOPR proposal to
allow a small power production facility
seeking QF status to provide further
information in its certification (both
self-certification and application for
Commission certification) or
recertification (both self-recertification
and application for Commission
recertification) to preemptively defend
against rebuttal, by identifying factors
that affirmatively show that its facility
is indeed at a separate site from
797 Definitionally, if the facilities are not owned
by the same person(s) or its affiliates, then the issue
of compliance with the one-mile rule, even as
revised in this final rule, becomes irrelevant. See 18
CFR 292.204(a)(1). That is, two facilities owned by
two different persons are definitionally not located
at the same site.
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
54702
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
affiliated small power production QFs
more than one but less than 10 miles
away from it. Any party challenging the
QF certification (both self-certification
and application for Commission
certification) or recertification (both
self-recertification and application for
Commission recertification) that makes
substantive changes to the existing
certification would, in its protest, be
allowed to correspondingly identify
factors to show that the small power
production facility seeking QF status
and affiliated small power production
QFs more than one but less than 10 from
that facility are actually at the same site.
511. We reiterate that, as a general
matter, no one factor is dispositive.798
Rather, we will conduct a case-by-case
analysis, weighing the evidence for and
against, and the more compelling the
showing that affiliated small power
production QFs should be considered to
be at the same site as the small power
production facility seeking QF status in
a specific case, the more likely the
Commission will be to find that the
facilities involved in that case are
indeed located ‘‘at the same site.’’
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
g. Exemptions
i. Comments
512. Ares notes that small power
producers have certain exemptions from
utility regulation, including exemptions
from FPA sections 203 and 204 if under
30 MW and exemptions from FPA
sections 205 and 206 if under 20 MW
(or 30 MW in special cases), as well as
exemptions from some state utility laws
and PUHCA if under 30 MW.799 Ares is
concerned that the rebuttable
presumption and the factors will make
many small power QFs ineligible for
these exemptions.800 Ares argues that
the aggregation of small power QFs may
result in many required applications for
market-based rate authority for sales
that are minor. Ares argues that the
Commission has no basis for, did not
consider, and has sought no comments
on the removal of regulatory obligations
when small power QFs are aggregated
under the new ten-mile proposal.801
513. Solar Energy Industries note that
many facilities could lose their FPA and
PUHCA exemptions if there are multiple
facilities within 10 miles, which is
particularly harmful to QFs that are not
selling to their host utility. Solar Energy
Industries state that PURPA section
210(e)(1) instructs that the Commission
shall exempt QFs from regulation if
such exemption ‘‘is necessary to
encourage cogeneration and small
power production.’’ 802
would properly not be entitled to the
exemptions that are available to QFs.
ii. Commission Determination
2. Electrical Generating Equipment
514. The Commission’s current onemile rule is a rule used to measure,
ultimately, whether or not small power
production facilities are within
PURPA’s limit on small power
production QFs of 80 MW, and thus
whether such facilities are QFs, and the
Commission has consistently applied
the one-mile rule generally to the
regulations issued pursuant to
PURPA.803 There is no persuasive
reason it should not be equally applied
in the context of the regulations
implementing section 210(e) of PURPA.
That being said, we are not removing or
amending the exemptions provided by
the regulations implementing PURPA
section 210(e). If a QF qualifies for
exemptions pursuant to PURPA section
210(e) and the Commission’s
implementing regulations,804 then that
QF is entitled to those exemptions. But,
if a small power production facility does
not meet the 80 MW limit for whatever
reason, including because an affiliated
small power production QF is located at
the same site, then it does not qualify
for such exemption because it would
not be a QF.805 There is nothing
inappropriate about this consequence; a
facility that is not a QF is not entitled
to the exemptions available to QFs. We
further note that there will now be a
rebuttable presumption that affiliated
small power production QFs located
more than one but less than 10 miles
apart are indeed located at separate
sites. That is no different than the onemile rule as it has long existed. What is
different is that, with this final rule, the
presumption will be rebuttable while
before it was irrebuttable; the
presumption that the facilities are at
separate sites, though, remains
unchanged. Only if a party rebuts that
presumption and shows that the small
power production facility seeking QF
status and affiliated small power
production QFs should be viewed as
located at the same site will the capacity
of such facilities be counted together. In
that event, if the small power
production facility seeking QF status
and affiliated small power production
QFs located at the same site have a
combined power production capacity
that exceeds 80 MW, the entity seeking
QF status would not qualify as a QF and
a. NOPR Proposal
515. The Commission proposed
defining ‘‘electrical generating
equipment’’ to refer to all boilers, heat
recovery steam generators, prime
movers (any mechanical equipment
driving an electric generator), electrical
generators, photovoltaic solar panels
and/or inverters, fuel cell equipment
and/or other primary power generation
equipment used in the facility,
excluding equipment for gathering
energy to be used in the facility. The
Commission expected that each wind
turbine on a wind farm and each solar
panel in a solar facility would be
considered ‘‘electrical generating
equipment’’ because each wind turbine
and each solar panel is independently
capable of producing electric energy.
The Commission sought comments on
this approach, and on what
equipment—if not individual wind
turbines and solar panels—should be
considered ‘‘electrical generating
equipment’’ for wind and solar plants.
516. The Commission also proposed
specifying how to measure the distance
between facilities that have multiple,
separate sets of ‘‘electrical generating
equipment’’ such as wind farms and
solar facilities. The Commission
proposed measuring the distance
between the nearest ‘‘electrical
generating equipment’’ of any two
facilities such that, for the facilities to
be presumed irrebuttably separate, all
such equipment of one QF must be at
least 10 miles away from all such
equipment of another QF. The
Commission believed this is the
appropriate way to measure the distance
between affiliated sets of ‘‘electrical
generating equipment’’ because this
reflects the distance between the
components directly tied to producing
electric energy.
517. The Commission sought
comment on this approach, and whether
alternative approaches would be more
appropriate. For example, some parties
had suggested in QF certification
proceedings that the Commission could
use the geographic center of the plant
footprint or a weighted average of the
locations of the individual pieces of
‘‘electrical generating equipment.’’ 806
The Commission was concerned these
approaches could be easily gamed, but
sought comment on whether they may
be constructed in a way that would
prevent gaming, and whether such
802 Solar
Energy Industries Comments at 55.
B9 Holdings LLC, 157 FERC ¶ 61,044, at
P 16 & n.24 (2016) (citing Windfarms, 13 FERC
¶ 61,017 at 61,031).
804 18 CFR 292.601, 292.602.
805 See 16 U.S.C. 796(17)(A)(ii).
803 SunE
798 But
see supra note 797.
Comments at 4–5.
800 Id. at 5–6.
801 Id. at 11–12.
799 Ares
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
PO 00000
Frm 00066
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
806 See Beaver Creek Wind II, LLC, 160 FERC
¶ 61,052, at P 9 (2017).
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
formulations would be preferable to the
proposed approach.
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
b. Comments
518. Many commenters support the
definition of ‘‘electrical generating
equipment’’ proposed in the NOPR.807
However, ELCON objects to both the
proposed definition of ‘‘electric
generating equipment’’ and the
approach to measuring distance.808
519. Many commenters support the
method for measuring distance between
sites proposed in the NOPR, which
would require measuring the distance
between the nearest ‘‘electrical
generating equipment’’ of any two
affiliated facilities.809 Several
commenters note their opposition to
measuring the distance between sites
using the geographic center of the plant
or a weighted average of the locations of
individual pieces of ‘‘electrical
generating equipment,’’ both methods
the Commission sought comment on in
the NOPR.810 The Southeast Public
Interest Organizations request
clarification of whether to measure from
the edge of a solar panel or the center
of a solar array.811
520. Several commenters request that
the Commission discuss how energy
storage (sometimes referred to as battery
storage) would be considered in relation
to the proposed definition of electrical
generating equipment.812 The California
Commission requests that a battery
storage facility be excluded from
consideration as electrical generating
equipment provided the storage is
charged solely by the small power
production facility, and that energy
stored by the storage facility be
considered to be of the same energy
source of that energy before it was
stored.813 The California Commission
807 Alliant Energy Comments at 19; APPA
Comments at 23; Basin Comments at 11;
Connecticut Authority Comments at 19–20; EEI
Comments at 49; Idaho Commission Comments at
6; Kentucky Commission Comments at 7; NRECA
Comments at 17; Portland General Comments at 16–
17; Southeast Public Interest Organizations
Comments at 37–38.
808 ELCON Comments at 36.
809 Alliant Energy Comments at 19; APPA
Comments at 23; Basin Comments at 11;
Connecticut Authority Comments at 19–20; EEI
Comments at 49; Kentucky Commission Comments
at 7; NARUC Comments at 4–5; Portland General
Comments at 16–17; Southeast Public Interest
Organizations Comments at 37–38.
810 Connecticut Authority Comments at 21;
Kentucky Commission Comments at 7;
NorthWestern Comments at 12–13; NRECA
Comments at 18; Portland General Comments at 18.
811 Southeast Public Interest Organizations
Comments at 38.
812 Alliant Energy Comments at 19; EEI
Comments at 46–47; Energy Storage Comments at
3; NorthWestern Comments at 13.
813 California Commission at 16–17.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
also requests that the Commission
affirm that storage does not permit a
facility to exceed the maximum size
criteria of a small power production
facility.814 EEI requests that the Form
556 collect data on storage resources as
well as electrical generating equipment
for purposes of measuring distance to an
affiliated small power production QF.815
c. Commission Determination
521. We adopt the NOPR proposal
that ‘‘electrical generating equipment’’
refers to all boilers, heat recovery steam
generators, prime movers (any
mechanical equipment driving an
electric generator), electrical generators,
photovoltaic solar panels, inverters, fuel
cell equipment and/or other primary
power generation equipment used in the
facility, excluding equipment for
gathering energy to be used in the
facility. Each wind turbine at a wind
facility and each solar panel in a solar
facility would be considered ‘‘electrical
generating equipment’’ because each
wind turbine and each solar panel is
independently capable of producing
electric energy.
522. We require the distance between
the facility seeking small power
production QF status and any affiliated
small power production QFs using the
same energy resource to be measured by
the distance between the nearest
‘‘electrical generating equipment’’ of
each such facility, such that, for the
entity seeking QF status to be presumed
irrebuttably at a separate site from any
affiliated small power production QF,
all such equipment of the affiliated
small power production QF must be at
least 10 miles away from all such
equipment of the entity seeking small
power production QF status. The
Commission finds that this is the most
appropriate way to measure the distance
between affiliated sets of ‘‘electrical
generating equipment’’ at small power
production facilities because this
reflects the distance between the
components directly tied to producing
electric energy.
523. The point used in the distance
calculation will always be from the edge
of the electrical generating equipment
closest to the affiliated small power
production QF’s nearest electrical
generating equipment. Thus, we clarify
that for a solar facility, the measurement
should be from the edge of the small
power production facility seeking QF
status’ solar panel or inverter that is
closest to the edge of the nearest
‘‘electrical generating equipment’’ of
that affiliated small power production
814 Id.
at 15.
at 51–52.
815 EEI
PO 00000
Frm 00067
Fmt 4701
QF. For a wind facility, the
measurement should similarly be from
the edge of the small power production
facility seeking QF status’ wind turbine
or inverter closest to the edge of the
nearest ‘‘electrical generating
equipment’’ of the affiliated small
power production QF. For a wind
facility, we clarify that the relevant
point for measuring distance of an
individual wind turbine is the tower
(not the projection of the blade’s
wingspans onto the ground). We also
clarify that only horizontal distances are
taken into consideration for purposes of
this rule (such that elevation changes
have no effect on facility distance).
524. We find that the role of battery
storage in QFs, including with regard to
the distance between QFs, is beyond the
scope in this proceeding.
E. QF Certification Process
1. NOPR Proposal
525. In the NOPR, the Commission
proposed to revise 18 CFR 292.207(a) to
allow interested persons to intervene in,
and to file a protest of a self-certification
or self-recertification of a facility
without the necessity of filing a separate
petition for declaratory order and
without having to pay the filing fee
required for a declaratory order. Because
an applicant for self-certification or selfrecertification is required to serve a
copy of its submission on interested
electric utilities (principally those with
which it is interconnected and those to
which it will be selling) as well as the
relevant state regulatory authorities, the
Commission proposed to allow
interested persons 30 days from the date
of filing at the Commission to intervene
and/or to file a protest (without paying
a filing fee).816
526. Any party submitting a protest
would have the burden of specifying
facts that make a prima facie
demonstration that the facility described
in the self-certification or selfrecertification does not satisfy the
requirements for QF status. General
allegations that the facility is not a QF
without reference to the specific
regulatory provision that has not been
satisfied (and without an explanation
why the provision has not been
satisfied), or unsupported assertions
that the self-certification does not satisfy
an aspect of the PURPA Regulations,
would not satisfy this burden and
would not be a basis for denial of
certification. However, if this prima
facie burden is met, then the burden
would shift to the applicant submitting
the self-certification or self816 18
Sfmt 4700
54703
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
CFR 292.207(c)(1).
02SER2
54704
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
recertification to demonstrate that the
claims raised in the protest are incorrect
and that certification is, in fact,
warranted.
527. QF self-certification is effective
upon filing and would remain effective
if a protest is filed, until such time as
the Commission rules that certification
is revoked. The Commission proposed
that it would issue an order within 90
days of the date the protest is filed. The
Commission also reserved the right to
request more information from the
protester, the entity seeking QF status,
or both.817 If the Commission requests
more information, the time period for
the Commission order would be
extended to 60 days from the filing of
a complete answer to the information
request.
528. There may be instances,
however, when the Commission may
need additional time to review the
record in light of the nature of the
protests. In those cases, the Commission
proposed that, in addition to any
extension resulting from a request for
information, the Commission also may
toll the 90-day period during which the
Commission commits to act within one
additional 60-day period. The
Commission proposed to delegate to the
Commission’s Secretary, or the
Secretary’s designee, the authority to
toll the 90-day period for this purpose.
529. The Commission believed these
procedures would allow for timely but
thorough review of protested selfcertifications and self-recertifications.
The Commission sought comment on
whether these procedures impose an
undue burden on the QF even though
the QF remains certified pending the
review.
2. Comments
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
530. Many commenters raise the issue
of granting legacy treatment,
colloquially known as ‘‘grandfathering,’’
to existing QF certifications and their
future recertifications.818 Most of these
comments support granting legacy
treatment to current QFs and their
817 Such information requests could be issued by
the Commission or by staff under any applicable
delegated authority. For example, under 18 CFR
375.307(b)(3)(ii), the Director of the Office of Energy
Market Regulation is authorized to ‘‘[i]ssue and sign
requests for additional information regarding
applications, filings, reports and data processed by
the Office of Energy Market Regulation.’’
818 Ares Comments at 12; Basin Comments at 11;
BluEarth Comments at 2; DC Commission at 9; New
England Small Hydro Comments at 17; Industrial
Energy Consumers Comments at 17; NIPPC, CREA,
REC, and OSEIA Comments at 74; Solar Energy
Industries Comments at 61–63; SC Solar Alliance
Comments at 18; Southeast Public Interest
Organizations Comments at 29–31; Terna Energy
Comments at 16–18.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
future recertifications.819 Several
commenters note that the application of
the rule to existing or recertifying QFs
will create uncertainty and cause
disruptions of the sale of these QFs.820
531. New England Small Hydro warns
that applying the proposed rule to
existing QFs could trigger financing
defaults if those QFs lose their status.821
The Southeast Public Interest
Organizations state that the proposed
rebuttable presumption has implications
for existing solar QFs in the Southeast,
noting that QFs would be required to
seek recertification as their existing
PPAs expire, adding a significant
burden.822 The Southeast Public Interest
Organizations provide maps showing
the ten-mile radius of utility-scale
projects could lead to many overlapping
affiliated territories under the new
rules.823 SC Solar Alliance also notes
the large number of small solar QFs
overlapping within a ten-mile radius
across North Carolina and South
Carolina and finds that the application
of the more-than-one-but-less-than-10miles rebuttable presumption to
recertifications will be burdensome and
unwieldy.824 NIPPC, CREA, REC, and
OSEIA warn that the application of the
new rule to existing QFs will effectively
bar the transfer or sale (or potentially
any number of less significant changes)
of existing assets that were lawfully
qualified under the one-mile rule but
would pass the 80 MW aggregate
threshold under the new rule. NIPPC,
CREA, REC, and OSEIA find this to be
a violation of the existing QFs
contractual and constitutional rights.825
532. Terna Energy states that granting
legacy treatment to existing QFs and
their recertifications is necessary to
protect investment decisions and
contracts made under the long-standing
one-mile rule.826 Terna Energy contends
that, without clarification on the legacy
treatment of recertifications, QFs could
lose their status even for nonsubstantive revisions to their FERC
Form No. 556s such as contact
819 Ares Comments at 12; BluEarth Comments at
2; New England Small Hydro Comments at 17;
Industrial Energy Consumers Comments at 17;
NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 74;
Solar Energy Industries Comments at 61–63; SC
Solar Alliance Comments at 18; Southeast Public
Interest Organizations Comments at 29–31; Terna
Energy Comments at 16–18.
820 New England Small Hydro Comments at 17;
NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 74;
Terna Energy Comments at 16–18.
821 New England Small Hydro Comments at 17.
822 Southeast Public Interest Organizations
Comments at 29.
823 Id. at 30–31.
824 SC Solar Alliance Comments at 18.
825 NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at
75.
826 Terna Energy Comments at 1–2.
PO 00000
Frm 00068
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
information, street address, ownership
or operation.827 Terna Energy warns that
absent the clarification of legacy
treatment for existing QF
recertifications, QFs might go to
extremes to avoid updating their FERC
Form No. 556s with information
changes.828
533. Solar Energy Industries state that
retroactively applying a more-than-onebut-less-than-10-miles rebuttable
presumption to physical facilities that
were developed based on the original
one-mile rule will inject instability, will
erode trust from the investment
community, and will discourage the
development of QFs as well as
investment in the industry in general.829
Ares notes that not granting legacy
treatment to existing QFs is inconsistent
with past Commission actions on
PURPA, such as the granting of legacy
treatment to existing QF contracts in
Order No. 671 or other QF related
proceedings.830
534. New England Small Hydro
supports granting legacy treatment to
existing QFs to avoid upsetting the
settled expectations of existing
generation.831 New England Small
Hydro gives the example of three
hypothetical projects, each located nine
miles apart that, when capacities are
totaled, exceed 80 MW. If there is an
ownership change that triggers the need
for a recertification but the entities
remain affiliates, under the
Commission’s proposed rule, all three
projects would lose QF status.
According to New England Small
Hydro, this could trigger defaults under
financing documents and the utility
might be able to terminate the power
contract, because many PPAs for QFs
require the project to remain a QF for
the term of the PPA. New England Small
Hydro states that, as a result, a minor
ownership change could have cascading
negative effects to QFs.832
535. Terna Energy requests that
existing QFs be granted legacy treatment
as long as they do not make changes to
electrical generating equipment of the
facility, because that is the equipment
that determines compliance with the
one-mile rule. Terna Energy argues that
otherwise an existing QF could be
subject to challenge anytime it makes a
non-substantive revision to its FERC
Form No. 556, including a change to
contact information, street address,
ownership, or operator, effectively
827 Id.
at 2.
at 7.
829 Solar Energy Industries Comments at 62.
830 Ares Comments at 12.
831 New England Small Hydro Comments at 17.
832 Id.
828 Id.
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
eliminating legacy treatment.833 Terna
Energy states that granting legacy
treatment is necessary to protect the
sanctity of investments and contracts
made in reliance upon the
Commission’s current PURPA
regulations and the one-mile rule.834
Terna Energy submits revised language
for 18 CFR 292.204(a)(2) and (3) to
clarify that existing QF recertifications,
unless they change the electrical
generating equipment, should not be
subject to the new rules.835
536. Basin, on the other hand, asks
the Commission to be clear that
recertifications filed by QFs will trigger
application of the proposed rule.836
Basin also recommends the Commission
allow petitions seeking de-certification
of QFs that have previously filed selfcertifications because some QFs selfcertify at an early stage of project
development and ultimately never
proceed to development.837
537. The DC Commission would like
the Commission to clarify whether the
changes to the one-mile rule will apply
to QFs under construction when the
rule goes into effect.838 The DC
Commission would like the Commission
to leave the issue of legacy treatment of
existing QFs up to the states.839
538. Several commenters oppose the
NOPR proposal to allow a party to
protest a self-certification or selfrecertification of a facility without being
required to file a separate petition for
declaratory order and pay the associated
filing fee.840 Several commenters argue
that this proposal will lead to a flood of
challenges that will discourage the
growth of QFs.841 Several commenters
state that there will be substantial costs
associated with this proposal that will
fall on ratepayers and QFs.842 Several
commenters state that the proposed
changes will lead to increased
administrative burden and expense 843
833 Terna
Energy Comments at 2.
at 1–2.
835 Id. at 8–9.
836 Basin Comments at 11.
837 Id.
838 DC Commission Comments at 9.
839 Id.
840 Allco Comments at 21; BluEarth Comments at
3; CARE Comments at 7; Con Edison Comments at
5; Distributed Sun Comments at 3; ENGIE
Comments at 4; Public Interest Organizations
Comments at 9, 97–98; Western Resource Councils
Comments at 144; Solar Energy Industries
Comments at 57–59.
841 Allco Comments at 21; BluEarth Comments at
3; Distributed Sun Comments at 3; Public Interest
Organizations Comments at 97; Western Resource
Councils Comments at 144.
842 Con Edison Comments at 5; ENGIE Comments
at 4; Public Interest Organizations Comments at 97;
Solar Energy Industries Comments at 58.
843 Ares Comments at 6; Borrego Solar Comments
at 4; Con Edison Comments at 5; Public Interest
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
834 Id.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
or litigation risk.844 Several commenters
state that the proposed changes will
lead to uncertainty 845 and deter
development.846
539. Solar Energy Industries state that
the proposed changes to the one-mile
rule will substantially increase the
regulatory burden on QFs and the selfcertification process will no longer be
quick.847 Solar Energy Industries is
concerned that QFs may need to defend
numerous self-certifications over a
facility’s lifetime, and assert that QFs
could be forced to recertify any time the
information represented in the Form No.
556 changes, including ownership
changes to affiliated facilities located
within 10 miles.848 Solar Energy
Industries state that the burden will be
increased exponentially if the one-mile
rule is expanded in a ten-mile rule.849
Solar Energy Industries state that the
NOPR’s estimate of an additional eight
hours and $632 per docket for each QF
self-certification or re-certification is a
substantial underestimation.850 Solar
Energy Industries estimate that it would
require an additional approximately 90
to 120 hours per year to comply with
the new requirements. Solar Energy
Industries state that a QF could be
forced to recertify any time the
information represented changes,
including ownership changes to
affiliated facilities located within 10
miles. Solar Energy Industries note that
a QF may have to engage in multiple
defenses of its status, each time needing
to engage legal counsel and devote
Organizations Comments at 97–98; Solar Energy
Industries Comments at 51–52, 54, 57–58; SC Solar
Alliance Comments at 15–18; Southeast Public
Interest Organizations Comments at 29, 35; sPower
Comments at 14.
844 Con Edison Comments at 5; Distributed Sun
Comments at 3; ELCON Comments at 19–20; NIPPC,
CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 71–72; Public
Interest Organizations Comments at 97–98; Solar
Energy Industries Comments at 58–60; SC Solar
Alliance Comments at 16, 18; Southeast Public
Interest Organizations Comments at 29,35; sPower
Comments at 14.
845 Ares Comments at 9; Distributed Sun
Comments at 3; ELCON Comments at 19–20, 38;
NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 69–
72; Public Interest Organizations Comments at 97–
98; Solar Energy Industries Comments at 58–60, 62–
63; SC Solar Alliance Comments at 16, 18;
Southeast Public Interest Organizations Comments
at 29, 35, 38, 93, 97–98; sPower Comments at 14.
846 Allco Comments at 16; Borrego Solar
Comments at 4–5; Biological Diversity Comments at
9; Con Edison Comments at 4–5; Distributed Sun
Comments at 3; NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA
Comments at 72–73; North Carolina DOJ Comments
at 8; Public Interest Organizations Comments at 93,
99; Solar Energy Industries Comments at 51–52, 59–
63; SC Solar Alliance Comments at 2, 18; Southeast
Public Interest Organizations Comments at 31–36,
38, 93.
847 Solar Energy Industries Comments at 52.
848 Solar Energy Industries at 57.
849 Id. at 53.
850 Id. at 52.
PO 00000
Frm 00069
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
54705
internal company resources to preserve
the status of its already-installed
plant.851 Solar Energy Industries assert
that the flood of self-certification filings
and updates would be a substantial
burden on Commission staff and
provide little value to the Commission
or the public.852 Solar Energy Industries
also state that, unless and until the
Commission makes a determination on
the burden associated with collecting,
reporting, and updating the Connected
Entity 853 information, it would be
unjust and unreasonable for the
Commission to impose similar burdens
on QF entities through the FERC Form
No. 556.854 Solar Energy Industries state
that the increased regulatory burden
that will arise for these entities is
similar in scope and the Commission
has not provided a rationale for the
increased information collection
requirements.855
540. Allco describes the
Commission’s Regulatory Flexibility Act
(RFA) analysis of the proposed rules’
effect on small businesses as improperly
limited to proposed paperwork changes,
ignoring the impact on small QFs’
abilities to construct facilities.856 Allco
states that the Commission did not
attempt to minimize the impacts on
small renewable energy producers,
consider alternative structures, or
describe these steps or considerations in
a mandatory final RFA analysis.857
Allco asserts that the Commission failed
to support its finding that the NOPR’s
proposed revisions will not significantly
impact a substantial number of small
entities (specifically, solar energy QFs);
Allco therefore claims that the
Commission violated the Small
Business Regulatory Enforcement
Fairness Act.858
541. Solar Energy Industries state that
the NOPR lacks important details such
as whether the Commission’s
determination is subject to rehearing,
and whether a final decision can be
appealed under the FPA to an appellate
court.859 Solar Energy Industries state
that an adverse determination by the
Commission could impose upwards of
$100 million in harm on a QF, and it is
unclear whether the QF would have a
path to relief if the Commission erred in
its determination. Solar Energy
851 Id.
at 58.
at 53–54.
853 Id. at 54 (citing Data Collection for Analytics
and Surveillance and Market-Based Rate Purposes,
Order No. 860, 168 FERC ¶ 61,039, at P 183 (2019)).
854 Id. at 54, 57.
855 Id. at 54.
856 Allco Comments at 33.
857 Id.
858 Id.
859 Id. at 58.
852 Id.
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
54706
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
Industries state that the current practice,
where the challenger bears the
responsibility of seeking declaratory
relief, strikes an appropriate balance.860
542. Several commenters, on the other
hand, support the NOPR proposal to
allow a party to protest a selfcertification or self-recertification of a
facility without being required to file a
separate petition for declaratory order
and to pay the associated filing fee.861
Several commenters argue that the
proposed amendment would strike the
right balance and distribute the burdens
of proof appropriately.862 Several
commenters also state that this proposal
would increase the efficiency of the
process, reduce administrative costs,
and could solve potential certification
problems before they even begin.863
543. Other commenters support the
NOPR proposal, but with caveats or
extra requests.864 Golden Valley
recommends that the 30-day clock to
challenge QF self-certification or selfrecertification begins when the QF
serves notice to the interested electric
utility, not when the QF makes its filing
with the Commission.865 NIPPC, CREA,
REC, and OSEIA state that the
Commission should provide a 60-day
deadline after the filings are complete
by which time a failure of the
Commission to rule results in the
objection being denied by operation of
law.866
544. NorthWestern requests the QFs
be subject to various discovery requests
when they self-certify or selfrecertify.867 Two commenters argue that
any challenging party should be
required to include an affidavit from a
company official.868
545. NorthWestern and Northern
Laramie Range Alliance request that QF
860 Id.
at 59.
Power Comments at 2; Alliant Energy
Comments at 22–23; APPA Comments at 31–35;
Duke Energy Comments at 23–24; Indiana
Municipal Comments at 10; NRECA Comments at
21–22; Portland General Comments at 21–22; Ohio
Commission Energy Advocate Comments at 10;
Chamber of Commerce Comments at 8; We Stand
Comments at 3.
862 APPA Comments at 31–35; NRECA Comments
at 21–22; Ohio Commission Energy Advocate
Comments at 10.
863 Indiana Municipal Comments at 10; NRECA
Comments at 21–22; Portland General Comments at
21–22.
864 DTE Electric Comments at 9–10; Golden
Valley Electric Comments at 1–2, 3–7; Industrial
Energy Consumers Comments at 14; Northern
Laramie Range Alliance Comments at 3;
NorthWestern Comments at 17–18; ELCON
Comments at 19–20, 37–38.
865 Golden Valley Electric Comments at 2.
866 NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at
74.
867 NorthWestern Comments at 17–18.
868 Industrial Energy Consumers Comments at 14;
ELCON Comments at 20, 38.
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
861 Alaska
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
developers seeking certification with the
Commission should be required to
publish notice in local newspapers in
the states in which the development
would be located, in order to alert
affected parties so they could intervene
in the certification process.869 El Paso
Electric is concerned by the proposal to
limit the ability to challenge QF status
once it has been certified in a
Commission certification proceeding or
in response to a challenge unless the
new challenger can demonstrate a
change in the facility circumstances that
threaten the validity of the previous
finding. El Paso Electric states that
sometimes QFs fail to provide utilities
with their QF application and so the
utility does not know to protest.870
546. Ares notes that small power
production QFs could be aggregated
under the more-than-one-but-less-than10-miles rebuttable presumption and
not even be aware of the other small
power production QFs because of a lack
of information.871
3. Commission Determination
547. We adopt the NOPR proposal to
revise 18 CFR 292.207(a) to allow an
interested person or entity to seek to
intervene and to file a protest of a selfcertification or self-recertification of a
QF, and not have to file a petition for
declaratory order and pay the filing fee
for petitions.872 We also adopt the other
changes to the QF certification process
proposed in the NOPR, with the
additions detailed below. We find that
any increased administrative burden or
litigation risk imposed by the new rule
is justified by the need to ensure that
QFs meet the statutory criteria for QF
status.
548. The ability to intervene and to
file a protest of a self-certification or
self-recertification of a QF without
having to file a petition for declaratory
order and pay the filing fee for petitions
is effective as of the effective date of the
final rule. However, we will grant legacy
treatment to existing QFs under certain
circumstances, as we explain below.
With the exceptions noted below,
protests pursuant to this final rule will
not be allowed to QF certifications and
recertifications (including selfcertifications and self-recertifications)
that are submitted before the effective
date of the final rule, although entities
may still challenge by filing a petition
869 NorthWestern Comments at 3; Northern
Laramie Range Alliance Comments at 3.
870 El Paso Electric Comments at 5.
871 Ares Comments at 6.
872 We amend the proposed regulation in the
NOPR to move the sections referring to protests and
interventions from 18 CFR 292.204 to 18 CFR
292.207.
PO 00000
Frm 00070
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
for declaratory order and submitting the
required fee. Conversely, protests can be
made to QF certifications (both selfcertification and application for
Commission certification) or
recertifications (both self-recertification
and application for Commission
recertification) that are submitted on or
after the effective date of this final rule.
We note here that it is the date of filing
for certification or recertification, and
not the date of construction, that
determines whether our new protest
rule applies to the certification or
recertification.
549. Many commenters have argued
for expansive legacy treatment for
recertification of existing projects. They
have noted that QFs need to recertify
when property is transferred, PPAs
expire, or even for non-substantive
changes, such as changes in contact
information or street address.873
Commenters argue that, if the new
protest rules apply to recertifications,
existing QFs could lose their QF status,
even if their configuration or other
relevant factors do not materially
change, when they file their
recertifications, upsetting the settled
expectations under which the QFs built
their facilities.
550. We agree that QF recertifications
to implement or address nonsubstantive changes should not be
subject to our new protest rule; the
settled expectations of the QFs should
be respected in such instances.
Accordingly, we find that protests may
be filed to an initial certification (both
self-certification and application for
Commission certification) filed on or
after the effective date of this final rule,
but only to a recertification (both selfrecertification and application for
Commission recertification) that makes
substantive changes to the existing
certification and that are filed on or after
the effective date of this final rule.
Substantive changes that may be subject
to a protest may include, for example,
a change in electrical generating
equipment that increases power
production capacity by the greater of 1
MW or 5 percent of the previously
certified capacity of the QF, or a change
in ownership in which an owner
increases its equity interest by at least
10% from the equity interest previously
reported. We find that recertifications
(both self-recertifications and
applications for Commission
recertifications) making ‘‘administrative
only’’ changes should not be subject to
873 NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at
75; Terna Energy Comments at 1–2, 7.
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
a protest pursuant to this final rule.874
We believe that excepting from protests
QF recertifications making nonsubstantive changes will allow QFs to
make such changes and recertify
without potentially losing their QF
status.
551. Solar Energy Industries asserts
that the certification process will no
longer be quick, and estimates that it
would require an additional
approximately 90 to 120 hours per year
to comply with these new requirements.
Solar Energy Industries is concerned
that QFs may need to defend numerous
self-certifications over a facility’s
lifetime, and asserts that QFs could be
forced to recertify any time the
information represented in the Form No.
556 changes.875
552. We do not agree with Solar
Energy Industries’ estimates. First, we
note that 18 CFR 292.207(d) (which we
are not altering in this rule except to
renumber as 18 CFR 292.207(f)) already
states that if a QF fails to conform with
any material facts or representations
presented in the certification, the QF
status of the facility may no longer be
relied upon,876 and hence it is longstanding practice that a QF must
recertify when material facts or
representations in the Form No. 556
change.
553. Second, certifications and
recertifications are already subject to
protests, albeit in the form of petitions
for declaratory order, and therefore
dealing with objections to a certification
or recertification is not new. Although
the new procedures may result in more
protests being filed than the number of
petitions that have been filed, we
believe that the conditions we impose in
this final rule will limit the number of
protests filed. The Commission
anticipates that most, though not all, of
the protests filed pursuant to the new 18
CFR 292.207(a) will relate to the new
more-than-one-but-less-than-10-miles
rebuttable presumption.877 Such
protests will necessarily be limited
because not all certifications and
recertifications will be subject to the
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
874 As
noted elsewhere in this final rule, our
allowing protests does not eliminate the ability to
file a petition for declaratory order seeking
revocation of qualifying status.
875 Solar Energy Industries at 57.
876 18 CFR 292.207(d), which this final rule will
renumber to 18 CFR 292.207(f).
877 While we anticipate that most protests will
involve interested persons or entities attempting to
rebut the presumption of separate sites for affiliated
small power production qualifying facilities that are
more than one and less than 10 miles apart, we note
that protesters may also protest any fact or
representation in the Form No. 556, or other aspect
of a QF’s filing they believe is inconsistent with
PURPA or our PURPA Regulations.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
new more-than-one-but-less-than-10miles rebuttable presumption. Only
small power production facilities
seeking QF status that have an affiliated
small power production QF more than
one but less than 10 miles away and that
uses the same energy resource are
subject to the rebuttable presumption.
Small power production facilities that
do not have multiple small power
production facilities or affiliates will not
be affected by the new rebuttable
presumption. Nor will cogeneration QFs
be affected by the new rebuttable
presumption.878 Additionally, in
general as described above, protests may
only be made to an initial certification
(both self-certification and application
for Commission certification) filed on or
after the effective date of this final rule,
and only to a recertification (selfrecertification or application for
Commission recertification) that makes
substantive changes to the existing
certification that are filed after the
effective date of this final rule.
554. Third, we are also instituting
time limits on protests that may be filed
under this final rule. We adopt the
NOPR proposal that interested parties
will have 30 days from the date of the
filing of the Form No. 556 at the
Commission to file a protest (without
paying a fee).879 Additionally, a
protestor must concurrently serve its
protest on the Form No. 556 applicant
pursuant to 18 CFR 385.2010.
555. Fourth, regarding Solar Energy
Industries’ concern that a QF may have
to engage in multiple defenses of its
status, in addition to the above limits on
protests, once the Commission has
affirmatively certified an applicant’s QF
status in response to a protest opposing
a self-certification or self-recertification,
or in response to an application for
Commission certification or
Commission recertification, any later
protest to a recertification (selfrecertification or application for
Commission recertification) making
substantive changes to a QF’s existing
certification, e.g., asserting that the
entity seeking QF status is at the same
site as affiliated small power production
QFs more than one but less than 10
miles from it, must demonstrate
changed circumstances from the facts on
878 The 80 MW limit and same site determination
only apply to small power production facilities, not
cogeneration facilities. See 16 U.S.C. 796(17)(A).
879 We note that section 292.207(c) of the PURPA
Regulations requires the applicant to concurrently
with its filing serve a copy of the filing on each
applicable electric utility as well as the applicable
State regulatory authority. We expect an applicant
seeking QF status (or recertifying its status) to
timely comply with that regulation. Therefore, a
utility should also receive the filing at the same
time that the filing is made at the Commission.
PO 00000
Frm 00071
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
54707
which the Commission acted on the
certification filing that call into question
the continued validity of the earlier
certification.
556. Finally, even if it indeed takes
some small power production facilities
an additional 90 to 120 hours (and we
think that unlikely), that is not an
unreasonable burden to impose to
ensure that a generating facility that
seeks to be a QF is, in fact, entitled to
QF status and complying with
PURPA.880
557. Turning to the requirements for
a protest, as proposed in the NOPR, we
will require any person or entity filing
a protest to specify facts that make a
prima facie demonstration that the
facility described in the certification
(both self-certification and application
for Commission certification) or
recertification (both self-recertification
or application for Commission
recertification) does not satisfy the
requirements for QF status. We will also
require any protest to be adequately
supported with any supporting
documents, contracts, or affidavits, as
appropriate. Just as public utilities are
typically not subject to discovery with
regard to their rate filings under section
205 of the FPA prior to the
Commission’s instituting trial-type
evidentiary hearings,881 we similarly
decline to make QFs subject to
discovery requests when they selfcertify or self-recertify.
558. The Commission also orders here
that an applicant’s response to a protest
will be allowed under 18 CFR
385.213(a)(2). By this final rule, we are
consistent with that regulation,
‘‘otherwise order[ing]’’ that such
answers may be filed. They will be due
no later than 30 days after the filing of
the protest.
559. Rooftop solar developers
frequently finance the initial
development of rooftop solar
photovoltaic (PV) systems of individual
homeowners, and then retain ownership
of such PV systems for extended periods
of time until the ownership is
880 The regulations adopted in this final rule
explicitly make self-certifications and selfrecertifications effective upon filing and allow them
to remain effective even if challenged until such
time as the Commission finds that a facility does
not qualify to be a QF. Additionally, entities
seeking QF status can file self-certifications years in
advance of facility operation, such that the few
months contemplated by the new process should
not cause delay. Finally, with regard to the time it
may take to fill in the Form No. 556, we note that
while an entity seeking QF status may choose to
preemptively defend against claims that it should
be considered to be at the same site as affiliated
small power production qualifying facilities located
more than one but less than 10 miles from it, this
is optional, not required.
881 18 CFR 385.401(a).
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
54708
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
eventually transferred to the relevant
homeowners. While these rooftop solar
PV systems are owned by the developer,
each individual rooftop solar PV system
would be considered affiliated electrical
generating equipment of every other
rooftop solar PV system owned by that
developer. When there are multiple coowned rooftop solar PV systems within
a mile, and thus at the same site, they
may exceed 1 MW and therefore be
required to file for certification or
recertification unless they receive a
waiver.882 Moreover, whenever they add
an additional rooftop solar PV system to
their portfolio, or alternatively transfer
the ownership of such a rooftop solar
PV system to the relevant homeowner,
their facility could be viewed as no
longer conforming with the material
facts in their prior certification or
recertification; thus they would need to
recertify.
560. Due to the unique nature of
rooftop solar PV developers, the
Commission finds the recertification
requirement for PV developers could be
unduly burdensome. Therefore, to
lessen the burden on such developers
when recertifying, we will permit
rooftop solar PV developers an
alternative option to file their
recertification applications. That is,
rather than be required to file for
recertification each time the rooftop
solar developer adds or removes a
rooftop facility, a rooftop solar PV
developer may recertify on a quarterly
basis. The filing would be due within 45
days after the end of the calendar
quarter. However, if in any quarter a
rooftop solar PV developer either has no
changes or only has changes of power
production capacity of 1 MW or less,
then it would not be required to
recertify until it has accumulated
changes greater than 1 MW total over
the quarters since its last filing.883
Additionally, we note that rooftop solar
PV developers, like all small power
production facilities, will not be subject
to protests when they file
recertifications that are ‘‘administrative
only’’ in nature, but would be subject to
such protests when they make
substantive changes to the existing
882 See
Sunrun, Inc., 167 FERC ¶ 61,059 (2019).
example, if a rooftop solar QF increases its
power production capacity by 0.9 MW in a quarter,
it would not need to file to recertify for that quarter.
However, if in the next quarter the rooftop solar QF
increased its power production capacity by 0.9 MW,
it would need to recertify for that quarter because
cumulatively over the quarters since its last filing
it has changed its power production capacity by
more than 1 MW (i.e., under this example the
rooftop solar QF changed its power production
capacity since its last recertification filing by 1.8
MW).
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
883 For
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
certification as detailed above in this
section.
561. We take this opportunity to
clarify that, when the Commission
issues an order revoking QF
certification, such order is subject to
rehearing and appeal pursuant to the
FPA.884 The Commission’s authority to
determine whether or not a facility is a
qualifying small power production
facility stems from PURPA section 201,
which amended FPA section 3 to add
paragraph (17).885 Similarly, FPA
section 3(18) grants the Commission
authority to determine whether a
cogeneration facility meets the
Commission’s requirements.886 Because
the Commission’s authority is grounded
in the FPA, the Commission’s order
revoking QF certification is subject to
rehearing and appeal pursuant to FPA
section 313.887
562. El Paso Electric states that
sometimes the utility does not know to
protest, because sometimes QFs fail to
provide utilities with their QF
application, and El Paso Electric is
therefore concerned by the
Commission’s proposal to limit protests
by requiring that once the Commission
has affirmatively certified an applicant’s
QF status, any later protest must
demonstrate changed circumstances. We
note that a QF that is filing a FERC Form
No. 556 is currently required by 18 CFR
292.207(c) (which we are not altering in
this rule except to renumber as 18 CFR
292.207(e)) to serve a copy on each
electric utility with which it expects to
interconnect, transmit or sell electric
energy to, or purchase supplementary,
884 Similarly, when the Commission issues an
order affirmatively certifying an applicant’s QF
status (in response to a protest opposing a selfcertification or self-recertification, or in response to
an application for Commission certification or
recertification), any party to that proceeding
aggrieved by the order, including the protestant,
may seek rehearing and appeal pursuant to the FPA.
885 16 U.S.C. 796(17). Section 3(17) of the FPA
mandates a size requirement for a small power
production facility: It must have ‘‘a power
production capacity which, together with any other
facilities located at the same site (as determined by
the Commission), is not greater than 80 megawatts.’’
886 16 U.S.C. 796(18).
887 16 U.S.C. 825l. The Commission has
previously entertained rehearing of an order
revoking QF status, Golden Valley Elec. Ass’n, Inc.,
167 FERC ¶ 61,208 (2019), reh’g denied, 170 FERC
¶ 61,025 (2020), and of an order denying petitions
to revoke QF status, N. Laramie Range All., 138
FERC ¶ 61,171, reh’g denied, 139 FERC ¶ 61,190
(2012), appeal dismissed, 733 F.3d 1030. There
have also been appeals of orders denying petitions
to revoke QF status. N. Laramie Range All. v. FERC,
733 F.3d 1030 (10th Cir. 2013) (dismissing appeal
on other grounds); Brazos Elec. Power Coop. Inc.,
v. FERC, 205 F.3d 235 (5th Cir. 2000) (denying
petition for review). Unlike PURPA section 210,
PURPA section 201 amends the FPA and is
therefore subject to FPA section 313. See Portland
Gen. Elec. Co. v. FERC, 854 F.3d 692, 700 (2017);
Midland Power Coop. v. FERC, 774 F.3d 1, 3 (2014).
PO 00000
Frm 00072
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
standby, back-up or maintenance power
from, and the state regulatory authority
of each state where the facility and each
affected utility is located. This final rule
does not change that requirement and
we expect applicants to timely comply
with that regulation. Should an issue
arise, though, the Commission can
address it on a case-by-case basis as the
circumstances warrant. Additionally,
we note that, if a self-certification or
self-recertification is not protested
within the 30 day-period permitted for
protests, then, just as it could prior to
this final rule, a challenger still has the
ability to file a petition for declaratory
order, with the filing fee, without being
required to show changed
circumstances to do so.
563. Regarding Basin’s request to
allow petitions seeking de-certification
of QFs that have previously filed selfcertifications and ultimately never
proceed to development,888 as we note
above we limit the ability to file a
protest (rather than a petition for
declaratory order, with the
accompanying filing fee) to within 30
days of the date of the filing of the selfcertification or self-recertification. If an
interested party would like to contest a
self-certification or self-recertification
later than 30 days after the date of its
filing, then the interested party may file
a petition for declaratory order with the
accompanying filing fee, just as they
could prior to the effective date of this
final rule.
564. We decline to adopt the requests
that QF developers seeking certification
with the Commission be required to
publish notice in local newspapers in
the states in which the development
would be located. We find that the
service requirement already in our
regulations cited above should serve to
provide adequate notice to affected
entities.
565. We decline to impose a 60-day
deadline after which a failure of the
Commission to rule on the protest
results in the protest being denied by
operation of law. Self-certification will
be effective upon filing and we adopt
the NOPR proposal that the selfcertifications will remain effective after
a protest has been filed, until such time
as the Commission issues an order
revoking certification. We also clarify
that self-recertifications will likewise
remain effective after a protest has been
filed, until such time as the Commission
issues an order revoking certification.
566. We also will adopt the NOPR’s
proposed timeline for issuance of an
order following protests to a QF selfcertification and self-recertification. The
888 Basin
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
Comments at 11.
02SER2
54709
Commission will issue an order within
90 days of the filing of a protest.
However, if the Commission requests
more information, the time period for
the Commission order would be
extended to 60 days from the filing of
a complete answer to the information
request. In addition to any extension
resulting from a request for information,
the Commission also may toll the 90day period during which the
Commission commits to act for one
additional 60-day period. We clarify,
however, that, absent Commission
action by the date of the expiration of
the tolling period, a protest will be
deemed denied, and the selfcertification or self-recertification will
remain effective. We find that this
timeline provides both QFs and other
interested persons with certainty about
the QFs’ status within a reasonable
amount of time.
567. Regarding Ares’ concern that
small power production QFs could be
aggregated under the new rule without
being aware of the other small power
production QFs with which they are
aggregated, the Commission notes that
this concern would only apply to small
power production facilities owned by
the same person or its affiliates; it is
unlikely that the owner(s) of one facility
would not be aware of other, affiliated
QFs. Furthermore, the presumption
continues to be that a small power
production facility seeking QF status
that is located more than one but less
than 10 miles from any affiliated small
power production QFs is at a separate
site from those affiliated small power
production QFs, and the Commission
here is simply making this presumption
rebuttable. If an entity challenges that
presumption, the applicant seeking QF
status would necessarily be served with
the protest 889 and thus informed of the
challenge, and given the opportunity to
defend against the challenge.
568. Regarding Solar Energy
Industries contention regarding the
currently pending Connected Entity
proceeding, that is a separate
proceeding and beyond the scope of this
proceeding. Moreover, the data
collection at issue in that proceeding
does not eliminate the need for the
Commission to collect the data required
by the FERC Form No. 556 so that the
Commission has the information it
needs to determine whether a facility
qualifies to be a QF consistent with the
standards laid out in the statute. In any
event, we note that the Connected Entity
rulemaking was about market-based rate
sellers, not QFs, and it is likely that the
Connected Entity rulemaking would not
apply to many QFs in the first place
since they often nether seek nor have
the authority to sell at market-based
rates.
569. Regarding Allco’s concerns about
the RFA, we discuss the RFA issue in
section VII.
571. The Commission proposed
adding a new item 8b,890 which would
be similar to the current item 8a, except
that it would cover affiliated facilities
whose nearest electrical generating
equipment is greater than 1 mile and
less than 10 miles from the electrical
generating equipment of the instant
facility.
572. The Commission proposed that
the instructions for the new item 8b
would also allow applicants with
facilities identified under item 8b (i.e.,
facilities more than one mile apart and
less than 10 miles apart) to, if they
choose, explain (in the Miscellaneous
section starting on page 19 of the form)
why the facilities identified under item
8b should be considered separate
facilities,891 considering the relevant
physical and ownership factors. The
Commission further proposed to
provide reference, in the instructions to
the new item 8b, to the paragraphs of
this final rule which discuss the
relevant physical and ownership factors
that may be asserted to defend against
rebuttal.
573. The Commission sought
comment on whether item 8a (existing)
should be revised and item 8b (as
proposed) written to require that the
applicant specify the distance from the
instant facility to each affiliated facility
listed. We also sought comment on
whether items 8a and (new) 8b should
require the applicant to document (in
the Miscellaneous section on page 19 of
the FERC Form No. 556) how the
distances reported were calculated.
Specifically, we sought comment on
whether the applicant should be
required to identify the particular
electrical generating equipment and
associated geographic coordinates used
890 Subsequent items in that section of the FERC
Form No. 556 would be retained but re-numbered
and moved down accordingly.
891 As discussed in detail in section IV.D.1.d, this
final rule will change the references to ‘‘separate
facilities’’ or ‘‘the same facility’’ to ‘‘at separate
sites’’ or ‘‘at the same site.’’
889 18
CFR 385.211(b).
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
PO 00000
Frm 00073
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
F. Corresponding Changes to the FERC
Form No. 556
1. NOPR Proposal
570. The Commission proposed
changes to the FERC Form No. 556,
corresponding to the new rules
discussed above regarding whether QFs
are at separate sites. Currently, item 8a
of FERC Form No. 556 requires that the
applicant identify any facilities with
electrical generating equipment within
one mile of the instant facility’s
electrical generating equipment, as
shown below:
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
ER02SE20.000
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
54710
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
in calculating the distance(s) between
the facilities.
574. The Commission noted that item
8a currently requires applicants to list
all affiliated ‘‘facilities.’’ Under this
requirement, an applicant would have
to list all affiliated QFs as well as
affiliated non-QFs. We requested
comment on whether such a
requirement is more burdensome than
necessary. It was not clear that requiring
the listing of affiliated non-QFs is
necessary in monitoring for compliance
with the relevant QF regulations, which
are concerned only with the distance
between affiliated QFs.
575. The Commission also sought
comment on whether item 3c
(geographic coordinates) and the
Geographic Coordinates instructions on
page 4 of the current FERC Form No.
556 should be modified such that
reporting of geographic coordinates
should be required for all applications,
rather than only for applications where
there is no facility street address (as has
been the case). We believed such
information may provide more
transparency in measuring distances
between facilities, and that such
transparency may be useful for both the
public and Commission staff in
monitoring compliance with the
Commission’s QF regulations.
576. The Commission noted, as it did
in Order No. 732,892 and as in the
general form instructions on page 4 of
the FERC Form No. 556, that such
coordinates can be obtained through
certain free online map services (with
links and instructions available through
the Commission’s QF website); GPS
devices (including smartphones, which
are now nearly ubiquitous); Google
Earth; property surveys; various
engineering or construction drawings;
property deeds; or municipal or county
maps showing property lines. The
Commission also noted that the
Commission has a link on its QF web
page (https://www.ferc.gov/industriesdata/electric/power-sales-and-markets/
purpa-qualifying-facilities) which
provides assistance with determining
geographic coordinates of facilities. As
such, the Commission believed that the
burden that would be created by
requiring every QF to provide
geographic coordinates would be
limited. Even so, the Commission
sought comment on whether the value
of the information to the public and the
892 Revisions to Form, Procedures, and Criteria for
Certification of Qualifying Facility Status for a
Small Power Production or Cogeneration Facility,
Order No. 732, 130 FERC ¶ 61,214, at P 100 (2010).
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
Commission would outweigh the
limited burden.
2. Comments
577. A few commenters oppose the
changes to FERC Form No. 556 as
proposed in the NOPR.893 Solar Energy
Industries and the Southeast Public
Interest Organizations contend that the
proposed new item 8b that requests a
list of all affiliated facilities within one
to 10 miles from the certifying QF
would be a significant increase in
information collection, time, effort, and
cost of QF certification.894
578. The Southeast Public Interest
Organizations further object that the
obligation to show how distances are
calculated and to identify electrical
generating equipment and their
associated geographic coordinates are
overly burdensome for facilities that are
presumed to be separate and contradicts
the rebuttable presumption of separate
facilities, which usually places the
burden on the challenger.895
579. The Southeast Public Interest
Organizations also assert it would be
reasonable to ask for only affiliated QFs
and to exclude non-QF affiliates from
the questions in item 8.896
580. Several commenters support
changes to FERC Form No. 556 as
proposed in the NOPR.897 A few
commenters support the proposed
changes to item 8a and proposed new
item 8b and argue that the additional
information might be otherwise difficult
to find and will be useful to clarify if the
assumption of separate facilities is
appropriate.898 Some commenters
support requiring all applicants to
supply geographic coordinates in item
3c, regardless of whether they have a
street address.899
581. Two commenters support the
collection of information for all
affiliated facilities, not just QF affiliates,
within the one or ten-mile radius
requested in item 8a and proposed item
8b, respectively, because they believe it
893 Solar Energy Industries Comments at 8;
Southeast Public Interest Organizations Comments
at 36–37.
894 Solar Energy Industries Comments at 56;
Southeast Public Interest Organizations Comments
at 36–37.
895 Southeast Public Interest Organizations
Comments at 37–38.
896 Id.
897 APPA Comments at 23; EEI Comments at 50;
Portland General Comments at 17–18; Subsurface
Engineering Association Comments at 1.
898 APPA Comments at 23–24; EEI Comments at
50.
899 EEI Comments at 50; Idaho Commission
Comments at 7; Subsurface Engineering Association
Comments at 1.
PO 00000
Frm 00074
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
will be needed to identify QFs not
complying with the proposed rule.900
582. Solar Energy Industries assert
that the proposed item 8b to the Form
No. 556, requiring a listing of all
affiliated facilities whose nearest
electrical generating equipment is
greater than one mile and less than 10
miles from the electrical generating
equipment of the certifying QF, is a
substantial expansion of the information
collection requirements and goes against
the Commission’s previously-granted
blanket exemptions for QFs to relieve
the burden of public utility regulation.
Solar Energy Industries argue that this is
not a mere information collection
requirement, but a request for
information that is not otherwise
publicly available and is inconsistent
with the Commission’s finding on the
burden of collecting Connected Entity
information. Solar Energy Industries
argue that collecting such information
from QFs is unwarranted discriminatory
treatment and is arbitrary and
capricious.901
583. A few commenters requested
additional changes to FERC Form No.
556.902 North American-Central would
like the Commission to create separate
Form No. 556 forms for small power
producers and cogeneration QFs for a
more distinct and simplified application
process.903 EEI would like Form No. 556
to explicitly include battery storage.904
EEI requests that the Form No. 556
collect information on the rated capacity
and notes that net capacity may not be
the appropriate measure of power
production. Solar Energy Industries also
noted that the Commission stated in
Order No. 732 that future changes to
Form No. 556 would not go through a
rulemaking and would instead be
reviewed by the Office of Management
and Budget with a period for public
comments.905
3. Commission Determination
584. We adopt the NOPR proposals
regarding changes to the FERC Form No.
556, with the further clarifications and
additions described below. The revised
Form No. 556 will be attached to this
rule in eLibrary, but will not be
published in the Federal Register or
Code of Federal Regulations. The
Commission finds that the added
information collected by these changes
900 EEI Comments at 50–51; Portland General
Comments at 18.
901 Solar Energy Industries Comments at 56–57.
902 EEI Comments at 51; El Paso Electric
Comments at 5–6; North American-Central
Comments at 7.
903 North American-Central Comments at 7.
904 EEI Comments at 51–52.
905 Solar Energy Industries Comments at 56.
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
is necessary to implement the changes
made to the regulations in this final
rule, and thus justifies the increase in
reporting burden.
585. The currently effective Form No.
556 contains a ‘‘Who Must File’’ section
which specifies when an applicant
seeking QF status or recertification of
QF status must file a self-certification,
and when such applicant is exempt
from the filing requirement. We will
revise the ‘‘Who Must File’’ section to
clarify that the exemption from the
requirement to complete or file a Form
No. 556 applies to an applicant seeking
QF status for a small power production
facility that, together with any affiliated
small power production QFs within one
mile of the entity seeking small power
production QF status, has a net power
production capacity of 1 MW or less.
While we did not seek comment on this
corrective change in the NOPR, this
change is consistent with the
Commission’s determination in SunE B9
Holdings LLC, 906 and serves to make
the Form No. 556 more transparent in
its application.
586. We also revise the ‘‘Who Must
File’’ section to include a
‘‘Recertification’’ section which
provides the text of revised 18 CFR
292.207(f), (previously 18 CFR
292.207(d)) which states that a QF must
file for recertification whenever the QF
‘‘fails to conform with any material facts
or representation presented . . . in its
submittals to the Commission.’’ 907
This addition does not alter our
recertification requirements, and we
include it here simply to make the Form
No. 556 clearer in its application.
587. The total burden estimates in the
‘‘Paperwork Reduction Act Notice’’
section of FERC Form No. 556 will be
updated based on the changes in this
final rule, to provide the following
estimates: 1.5 hours for selfcertifications of facilities of 1 MW or
less; 1.5 hours for self-certifications of a
cogeneration facility over 1 MW; 50
hours for applications for Commission
certification of a cogeneration facility;
3.5 hours for self-certifications of small
power producers over 1 MW and less
than a mile or more than 10 miles from
affiliated small power production QFs
that use the same energy resource; 56
hours for an application for Commission
certification of a small power
production facility over 1 MW and less
906 157 FERC ¶ 61,044 at P 16 (‘‘the one-mile rule
of section 292.204(a)(2) is a size determination
which the Commission has consistently applied
generally to the regulations pursuant to PURPA,
and which applies here to determining the
applicability of the less-than-1–MW exemption of
section 292.203(d)’’) (internal citations omitted).
907 18 CFR 292.207(d).
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
than a mile or more than 10 miles from
affiliated small power production QFs
that use the same energy resource; 9.5
hours for self-certifications of small
power producers over 1 MW with
affiliated small power production QFs
more than one but less than 10 miles
that use the same energy resource; 62
hours for an application for Commission
certification of a small power
production facility over 1 MW with
affiliated small power production QFs
more than one but less than 10 miles
that use the same energy resource.
588. We find that an explanatory
‘‘Protest to the Filing’’ section should be
added to the FERC Form No. 556 to note
that, pursuant to 18 CFR 292.207, an
interested person or entity has 30 days
from the date of the filing of the FERC
Form No. 556 to intervene or file a
protest. The ‘‘Protest to the Filing’’
section will state that the protestor must
concurrently serve a copy of such filing,
pursuant to 18 CFR 385.211(b), on the
Form No. 556 applicant. The ‘‘Protest to
the Filing’’ section will also state that
the Form No. 556 applicant will have 30
days to file any answer to a protest. The
‘‘Protest to the Filing’’ section will also
state that protests may be made to any
initial certification, and any
recertifications on or after the effective
date of this final rule making
substantive changes to the existing
certification, which may include, for
example, a change in electrical
generating equipment that increases
power production capacity by the
greater of 1 MW or 10 percent of the
previously certified capacity of the QF,
or a change in ownership in which an
owner increases their equity interest by
at least 10% from the equity interest
previously reported. The ‘‘Protest to the
Filing’’ section will note that
‘‘administrative only’’ changes will not
be subject to protests.
589. The Commission finds that item
3c (geographic coordinates) and the
Geographic Coordinates instructions on
page 4 of the current FERC Form No.
556 will be revised to require all
applicants to report the applicant
facility’s geographic coordinates, rather
than only for applications where there
is no street address (as was the case
previously). We find that such
information will provide more
transparency regarding the location of
each site, and that such transparency
may be useful for both the public and
Commission staff in monitoring
compliance with the Commission’s QF
regulations.
590. The Commission will change
item 8a, which currently requires
applicants to list all affiliated facilities
within one mile, to instead require that
PO 00000
Frm 00075
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
54711
the applicant only list affiliated small
power production QFs using the same
energy resource within one mile.
591. We modify the NOPR’s proposal
to add the collection of information for
affiliated facilities whose nearest
electrical generating equipment is more
than one but less than 10 miles from the
electrical generating equipment of the
applicant’s facility to instead add the
collection of information for affiliated
small power production QFs using the
same energy resource located more than
one mile but less than 10 miles from the
electrical generating equipment of the
applicant’s facility. However, rather
than adding a separate item 8b to the
Form No. 556 specifically for such QFs,
as proposed in the NOPR, we are
expanding the existing item 8a to
require the applicant to list all affiliated
small power production QFs using the
same energy resource whose nearest
electrical generating equipment is less
than 10 miles from the electrical
generating equipment of the entity
seeking small power production QF
status.
592. We determine that the revised
item 8a will require the applicant to list
the geographic coordinates of the
nearest ‘‘electrical generating
equipment’’ of both its own facility and
the affiliated small power production
QF in question based on the definitions
adopted in this final rule. The distance
between the entity seeking small power
production QF status and each affiliated
small power production QF will be
automatically calculated based on these
coordinates. For any affiliated small
power production QFs that cannot be
described in item 8a due to space
limitations, the instructions will direct
applicants to provide the required
information for such small power
production QFs in the Miscellaneous
section of the form. To facilitate the
uniform calculation of distances for
facility data that are entered into the
Miscellaneous section of the form, a
distance calculator will be added to the
form, and the form instructions will
direct applicants to use the calculator to
convert their facilities’ geographic
coordinates into distance.
593. The Commission also adopts the
NOPR proposal to allow applicants with
affiliated small power production QFs
greater than one mile and less than 10
miles from the electrical generating
equipment of the entity seeking small
power production QF status identified
under item 8a to, if they choose, explain
why the affiliated small power
production QFs greater than one mile
and less than 10 miles from the nearest
electrical generating equipment of the
entity seeking QF status identified
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
54712
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
under item 8a should be considered to
be at separate sites from the entity
seeking QF status, considering the
relevant physical and ownership factors.
The instructions will provide references
to the relevant physical and ownership
factors, as defined in this final rule, that
may be asserted to defend against
rebuttal.
594. Regarding Solar Energy
Industries’ concern regarding the
expansion of the information collection
requirements, we find that the added
information collected by item 8a of the
Form No. 556 is necessary to implement
the changes made to the regulations in
this final rule, and thus justifies the
increase in reporting burden. As noted
in section IV.E, the currently pending
Connected Entity proceeding is a
separate proceeding and beyond the
scope of this proceeding. Moreover, the
data collection at issue in that
proceeding does not eliminate the need
for the Commission to collect the data
required by the FERC Form No. 556 so
that the Commission has the
information it needs to determine
whether a facility qualifies to be a QF
consistent with the standards laid out in
the statute.
595. We note that these changes and
any future changes to Form No. 556 will
continue to be reviewed by the Office of
Management and Budget following
solicitation of comments from the
public, as described in Order No.
732.908
596. We find the requests for
additional changes to FERC Form No.
556 beyond the scope of this
proceeding.
G. PURPA Section 210(m) Rebuttable
Presumption of Nondiscriminatory
Access to Markets
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
1. PURPA Section 210(m)
Implementation
a. NOPR Proposal
597. In 2006, when Order No. 688 was
issued, the organized electric markets
had been in existence for only a few
years and were not well understood by
all market participants. Now, fourteen
years later, the markets are more mature,
and the mechanics of participation in
such markets are improved and better
understood. Consequently, in the NOPR,
the Commission determined that small
power production facilities below 20
MW should now be able to participate
in such markets under most
circumstances. The Commission
therefore proposed to revise 18 CFR
292.309(d) to reduce the net power
production capacity level at which the
908 Order
No. 732, 130 FERC ¶ 61,214.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
presumption of nondiscriminatory
access to a market attaches for small
power production facilities, but not
cogeneration facilities, from 20 MW to
1 MW.
598. The Commission determined
that, in light of the maturation of
organized electric markets, such a
reduction was consistent with
Congress’s intent to relieve electric
utilities of their obligation to purchase
when a QF has nondiscriminatory
access to competitive markets.
599. The Commission noted that, in
establishing the original presumption
that QFs whose net power production
capacity was 20 MW or below lacked
nondiscriminatory access to markets
defined in sections 210(m)(1)(A)–(C) of
PURPA, it had acknowledged that
‘‘there is no unique and distinct
megawatt size that uniquely determines
if a generator is small.’’ 909 The
Commission noted that, in using 20 MW
to separate the presumption that large
QFs had nondiscriminatory access and
small QFs lacked such access, the
Commission had recognized: (1) Order
No. 671’s exemption for QFs that are 20
MW or smaller from sections 205 and
206 of the FPA; and (2) Order Nos. 2006
and 2006–A’s setting 20 MW as the
demarcation for different
interconnection standards between
small and large generators.910 The
NOPR stated that, while the
Commission had not (and likewise did
not in the NOPR) propose to revise the
exemptions for QFs from sections 205
and 206 of the FPA, the Commission
had elsewhere taken steps to ease both
interconnection and market access for
generation resources with small
capacities since it first implemented
section 210(m) of PURPA.
600. For example, the Commission
noted that it had required public
utilities to provide a Fast-Track
interconnection process for some
interconnection customers whose
909 Order
No. 688–A, 119 FERC ¶ 61,305 at P 97.
Order No. 688, 117 FERC ¶ 61,078 at P 76,
order on reh’g, Order No. 688–A, 119 FERC ¶ 61,305
at P 97; see also 18 CFR 292.601(c)(1) (‘‘[S]ales of
energy or capacity made by qualifying facilities 20
MW or smaller, or made pursuant to a contract
executed on or before March 17, 2006 or made
pursuant to a state regulatory authority’s
implementation of section 210 the Public Utility
Regulatory Policies Act of 1978, 16 U.S.C. 824a–1,
shall be exempt from scrutiny under sections 205
and 206.’’); Revised Regulations Governing Small
Power Production and Cogeneration Facilities,
Order No. 671, 114 FERC ¶ 61,102, at P 98, order
on reh’g, Order No. 671–A, 115 FERC ¶ 61,225
(2006) (establishing exemption for QFs 20 MW or
below from 205 and 206 of FPA); Standardization
of Small Generator Interconnection Agreements and
Procedures, Order No. 2006, 111 FERC ¶ 61,220, at
P 75, order on reh’g, Order No. 2006–A, 113 FERC
¶ 61,195 (2005), order granting clarification, Order
No. 2006–B, 116 FERC ¶ 61,046 (2006).
910 See
PO 00000
Frm 00076
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
capacity is up to and including 5 MW
(up from the previous 2 MW
threshold),911 and had required each
RTO/ISO to revise its tariff to include a
participation model for electric storage
resources that establishes a minimum
size requirement for participation in the
RTO/ISO markets that does not exceed
100 kW.912 While both of these changes
do not apply only to generation types
that could become QFs or only to RTOs/
ISOs, the Commission stated that it
believed they generally show that small
power production facilities below 20
MW, specifically those whose capacity
exceeds 1 MW, now have greater access
to the markets defined in section
210(m)(1) of PURPA than they did when
the Commission first established the
presumptions of market access. The
Commission also stated that, under the
NOPR proposal and like QFs over 20
MW today, small power production
facilities over 1 MW would still be able
to rebut the presumption of access due
to operational characteristics or
transmission constraints.913
601. The Commission did not propose
to make the same reduction applicable
to cogeneration facilities. The
Commission stated that, unlike small
power production facilities, which are
constructed solely to produce and sell
electricity, cogeneration facilities
seeking QF certification after February
2, 2006 are statutorily required to show
that they are intended primarily to
provide heat for an industrial,
commercial, residential or institutional
process rather than fundamentally for
sale to an electric utility.914
Consequently, the production and sale
of electricity is a byproduct of these
thermal processes, and owners of
cogeneration facilities might not be as
familiar with energy markets and the
technical requirements for such sales.
The Commission stated that retention of
the existing 20 MW level for the
presumption of access to markets
therefore would be appropriate for
cogeneration facilities.
b. Comments in Opposition
602. Numerous commenters oppose
the NOPR proposal to revise 18 CFR
292.309(d) to reduce the net power
production capacity level at which the
presumption of nondiscriminatory
911 Small Generator Interconnection Agreements
and Procedures, Order No. 792, 145 FERC ¶ 61,159,
at P 103 (2013), clarifying, Order No. 792–A, 146
FERC ¶ 61,214 (2014).
912 Order No. 841, 162 FERC ¶ 61,127 at P 265.
913 See 18 CFR 292.309(c), (e), (f).
914 See 16 U.S.C. 824a–3(n); 18 CFR 292.205(d)(3).
We recognize that cogeneration facilities seeking
certification 5 MW or smaller after February 2, 2006
are presumed to satisfy this requirement. 18 CFR
292.205(d)(4).
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
access to a market attaches for small
power production facilities, but not
cogeneration facilities, from 20 MW to
1 MW.915
i. Insufficient Evidentiary Support
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
603. Several commenters argue that
the record does not support the
proposal.916
604. Advanced Energy Economy
asserts that, when an agency reverses
course on a policy issue, and the ‘‘new
policy rests upon factual findings that
contradict those which underlay’’ the
previous policy, then the agency must
‘‘provide a more detailed justification
than what would suffice for new policy
created on a blank slate.’’ 917 Advanced
Energy Economy argues that the NOPR
falls short of that standard.918
605. Public Interest Organizations and
NIPPC, CREA, REC and OSEI argue that
the Commission fails to cite any
evidence supporting the premise that
the markets are more mature, and that
the mechanics of participation in such
markets are improved and better
understood. Public Interest
Organizations and NIPPC, CREA, REC,
and OSEIA state that the Commission
asserts that QFs smaller than 20 MW
can now participate in markets on a
nondiscriminatory basis ‘‘under most
circumstances,’’ but that the
Commission does not explain what
those ‘‘circumstances’’ are, or whether
they apply as a general matter to most
small QFs.919
915 Allco Comments at 2, 17–19; Advanced
Energy Economy Comments at 1–12; AllEarth
Comments at 2; Biogas Comments at 2–3; Biological
Diversity Comments at 8–9; California Commission
Comments at 31–33; CARE Comments at 5–6; Con
Edison Comments at 5; Covanta Comments at 10–
12; DC Commission Comments at 4–5; Distributed
Sun Comments at 2–3; ELCON Comments at 18, 31–
35; Energy Recovery Comments at 4–5; ENGIE
Comments at 3–4; Commissioner Slaughter
Comments at 2, 4; Green Power Comments at 3;
Industrial Energy Consumers Comments at 6–10;
Massachusetts AG Comments at 6–8; Michigan
Commission Comments at 6–7; North AmericanCentral at 2–4; One Energy Comments at 2; South
Dakota Commission Comments at 5; Solar Energy
Industries Comments at 44–51; State Entities
Comments at 5–6; Western Resource Councils
Comments at 1–144.
916 AllEarth Comments at 2; Advanced Energy
Economy Comments at 5–9; Biological Diversity
Comments at 9; ELCON Comments at 31–32;
Industrial Energy Consumers Comments at 8; New
England Hydropower Comments at 11–12; NIPPC,
CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 77; Public
Interest Organizations Comments at 76–78; SC Solar
Alliance Comments at 12; Solar Energy Industries
Comments at 45–48; Southeast Public Interest
Organization Comments at 39–40.
917 Advanced Energy Economy Comments at 6
(citing FCC v. Fox Television Stations, Inc., 556 U.S.
at 515).
918 Id. at 7.
919 Public Interest Organizations Comments at 78;
NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 77
(citing NOPR, 168 FERC ¶ 61,184 at P 126).
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
606. Several commenters state that, in
Order No. 688–A, the Commission,
rejected utility proposals to set the
threshold at 1 MW, and confirmed that
20 MW was an appropriate threshold.920
Advanced Energy Economy states that
the Commission’s explanation in Order
No. 688–A, which stated that the
rebuttable presumptions were based on
the Commission’s experience of
implementing non-discriminatory open
access transmission over the past 11
years, dealing with QF issues over the
past 29 years and its experience with
RTO/ISO markets for almost 10 years,
contradicts the Commission’s
justification in the NOPR of limited
experience with organized electric
markets.921 Advanced Energy Economy
and Southeast Public Interest
Organizations assert that, since Order
No. 688, the Commission has repeatedly
found that utilities in organized markets
have failed to rebut the presumption of
nondiscriminatory access to QFs,
instead finding that QFs 20 MW and
under do not have sufficient access.922
607. Public Interest Organizations and
NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA argue
that the Commission fails to explain the
relevance of its Fast-Track
interconnection process or energy
storage order or which barriers these
developments alleviate for small QFs’
access to markets.923 Advanced Energy
Economy asserts that the expansion of
the Fast-Track procedures only applied
to a narrow slice of inverter-based
resources under 20 MW and is
insufficient to support a rebuttable
presumption that all QFs under 20 MW
have nondiscriminatory access.924
608. Solar Energy Industries and New
England Hydro argue that, just because
some small QFs participate in energy
markets, that is not sufficient
justification to find that all small QFs
meet the statutory standard required for
granting waiver for all QFs 20 MW or
less.925 Public Interest Organizations
920 Advanced Energy Economy Comments at 5–6;
ELCON Comments at 31–32.
921 Advanced Energy Economy Comments at 8–9.
922 Id. (citing, e.g., PPL Elec. Utils Corp., 145
FERC ¶ 61,053, at P 24 (2013); City of Burlington,
145 FERC ¶ 61,121, at P 36 (2013); Fitchburg Gas
and Elec. Light Co., 146 FERC ¶ 61,186, at PP 32–
33 (2014); Va. Elec. & Power Co., 151 FERC
¶ 61,038, at P 21 (2015); N. States Power Co., 151
FERC ¶ 61,110 (2015)); Southeast Public Interest
Organizations Comments at 39–40.
923 NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA at 77; Public
Interest Organizations Comments at 78 (citing Motor
Vehicle Mfrs. Ass’n of U.S., Inc. v. State Farm Mut.
Auto. Ins. Co., 463 U.S. 29, 43 (1983) (explaining
that an agency’s failure to consider the relevant
factors and supply a ‘‘rational connection between
the facts found and the choice made’’ renders its
decision arbitrary and capricious)).
924 Advanced Energy Comments at 7–8.
925 Solar Energy Industries Comments at 46; New
England Hydro Comments at 11–12.
PO 00000
Frm 00077
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
54713
assert that proper implementation of
section 210(m) requires that exemption
from the mandatory purchase obligation
only applies where QF development
will be stimulated by market forces;
otherwise Congress intended QF
development to continue to be
encouraged by the mandatory purchase
obligation.926 Protesters assert that the
record does not provide evidence that
could reasonably allow the Commission
to conclude that small QF development
will be stimulated by market forces. On
the contrary, the Public Interest
Organizations assert that the
Commission’s proposal placing the
burden on small QFs to rebut the
presumption of access is itself a barrier
to QF development.927
609. Solar Energy Industries argue
that, along with the energy markets, the
capacity markets in the RTO/ISO
regions have not evolved to provide a
meaningful opportunity for any QF to
sell long-term capacity.928 Solar Energy
Industries argue that PURPA section
210(m) requires the Commission to find
that a QF has nondiscriminatory access
to a market for long-term sales of
capacity prior to relieving the purchase
obligation. Solar Energy Industries
provide several examples such as
MISO’s Planning Resources Auction
that only provides a one-year purchase
agreement, PJM not purchasing capacity
since the Commission’s July 2019 Order,
and that SPP does not have a centralized
capacity market. Solar Energy Industries
argue that without a specific finding
that RTO/ISO markets provide QFs with
an opportunity to sell long-term
capacity, the Commission is statutorily
required to maintain utilities’ obligation
to purchase output from QFs 20 MWs or
less.929
610. Mr. Mattson asserts, without
elaboration, that FPA sections 205 and
206 disallow the Commission from
lowering the nondiscriminatory access
threshold from 20 MW to 1 MW, and,
therefore, claims it would amount to a
violation of state-jurisdictional rights
and a taking of property.930
ii. Administrative Burden and Complex
Market Rules
611. The DC Commission state that
QFs 20 MW or less lack the capability
926 Public Interest Organizations Comments at 76
(citing New PURPA Section 210(m) Regulations
Applicable to Small Power Production and
Cogeneration Facilities, Order No. 688, 117 FERC
¶ 61,078, at P 6 (2006), order on reh’g, Order No.
688–A, 119 FERC ¶ 61,305 (2007), aff’d sub nom.
Am. Forest and Paper Ass’n v. FERC, 550 F.3d
1179).
927 Id.
928 Solar Energy Industries Comments at 45.
929 Id. at 49.
930 Mr. Mattson Comments at 10.
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
54714
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
to participate in a complicated
wholesale market such as PJM where
there is a need to understand
membership obligations and rules in
order to appropriately execute
transactions.931
612. Allco argues that, in retail choice
states, PURPA is the only way small
QFs can sell to utilities. Allco asserts
that in retail choice states there is a
shifting retail customer base, therefore
utilities want obligations reduced and
contracts limited to a year. Allco asserts
that utilities and state commissions
cannot limit contracts due to a
potentially disappearing customer base
and then argue that a sufficient
wholesale market exists for long-term
sales of electric energy and capacity to
support nondiscriminatory access for
small QFs under 20 MW.932
613. Public Interest Organizations
argue that giving special exemptions to
cogeneration facilities is discriminatory
against small power producer QFs.933
Two commenters also assert that small
QFs are at an inherent disadvantage
compared to larger QFs because smaller
QFs are often engaged in other business
enterprises, such as governmental units
distributing irrigation water or local
companies unfamiliar with energy
markets.934
c. Comments in Support
614. Numerous commenters support
the proposal to revise 18 CFR 292.309(d)
for small power production facilities but
not cogeneration facilities, to reduce the
net power production capacity level at
which the presumption of
nondiscriminatory access to a market
applies from 20 MW to 1 MW.935 DTE
Electric argues that RTO/ISOs can now
provide smaller resources nondiscriminatory access, and therefore
931 DC
Commission Comments at 4–5.
Comments at 18.
933 Public Interest Organizations Comments at 74.
934 NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at
18–19, 24–25; Mr. Mattson Comments at 15.
935 Alliant Energy Comments at 13–16; Tax
Reform Comments at 2; APPA Comments at 24–26;
Arizona Public Service Comments at 8–10; Basin
Comments at 12–13; Freedom Center Comments at
2; Colorado Independent Energy Comments at 14;
Connecticut Commission Comments at 21–22;
Conservative Action Comments at 2; Consumers
Alliance Comments at 1–2; Consumers Energy
Comments at 4–5; DTE Electric Comments at 4–5;
East Kentucky Comments at 3; East River Comments
at 2; EEI Comments 54–59; FirstEnergy Comments
at 2–3; Idaho Power comments at 14; Indiana
Municipal Comments at 6–9; Institute for Energy
Research Comments at 2; Kentucky Commission
Comments at 8; Missouri River Energy Comments
at 3–4; NorthWestern at 14; TAPS Comments at 4;
Ohio Commission Energy Advocate Comments at 8;
Taxpayers Protection Alliance Comments at 2;
Chamber of Commerce Comments at 7; We Stand
Comments at 1–144; Taxpayer Protection Alliance
Comments at 2; TAPS Comments at 4.
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
932 Allco
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
electric utilities should no longer be
required to purchase electric energy
from them.936 EEI supports the proposal
because resource diversity has improved
and markets have evolved as smaller
resources, including QFs, are
increasingly participating in the RTO/
ISO markets. RTOs/ISOs have also
increasingly adjusted their bidding
rules, forecasts, and operations to better
accommodate variable resources.937
Alliant and the Ohio Commission
Energy Advocate state that small
resources have increased access to
wholesale markets and that RTO/ISO
rule flexibility allows for the nondiscriminatory participation of very
small resources and the aggregation of
even smaller resources in the markets,
therefore the 20 MW threshold is no
longer appropriate.938
615. Consumer Alliance and EEI argue
that reducing the threshold will reduce
costs to customers because currently
some QFs with access to markets are
foregoing the opportunity to participate
in those markets and electing to contract
with electric utilities under stateimplemented PURPA programs, which
EEI argues compensate QFs at an abovemarket rate.939
616. The Ohio Commission Energy
Advocate argues that the rebuttable
presumption process for QFs provides
an appropriate safety valve for the lower
threshold.940
d. Comments Requesting Modifications/
Clarifications
617. Institute for Energy Research
requests that the Commission expand
the rebuttable presumption of nondiscriminatory access to QFs 1 MW and
below if the market structure in a given
state is appropriate. Institute for Energy
Research gives the example of Texas’s
open market model, where generation is
open to all comers of all sizes. Institute
for Energy Research also suggests that
the Commission should include some
threshold now such that when other
states achieve similar open access
market designs QFs 1 MW and below
could be rebuttably presumed to have
non-discriminatory access to those
markets, without the need to undertake,
at that time, a separate rulemaking on
QFs 1 MW and below.941
618. The Connecticut Commission
suggests reducing the threshold at
936 DTE
Electric Comments at 5–6.
Comments at 56–58.
938 Alliant Energy Comments at 13–14; Ohio
Commission Energy Advocate Comments at 7–8.
939 EEI Comments at 58–59; Consumers Alliance
Comments at 1–2.
940 Ohio Commission Energy Advocate Comments
at 8.
941 Institute of Energy Research Comments at 2.
937 EEI
PO 00000
Frm 00078
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
which the presumption of
nondiscriminatory access attaches to 0
MW because the markets are more
mature, the mechanics of participating
in the markets are improved and the law
requires nondiscriminatory access to the
markets for all resources.942 Missouri
River Energy recommends lowering the
threshold to 500 kW.943 FirstEnergy
recommends the Commission treat both
small power production resources and
cogeneration resources consistently by
lowering the rebuttable presumption
threshold from 20 MW to 1 MW for all
QFs.944 Indiana Municipal requests that
the Commission automatically apply the
1 MW threshold to utilities that have
already been granted waiver for QFs
over 20 MW to promote the efficient use
of the Commission’s resources and
savings to utilities.945
619. The Michigan Commission
requests clarification on the NOPR
proposal specifically regarding: (1) How
existing contracts with QFs greater than
1 MW but below 20 MWs are to be
treated under the NOPR, and if they
would be subject to early termination or
would be granted legacy treatment
indefinitely or until the end of the
existing contract term; (2) whether
utilities that have already received relief
from the mandatory purchase obligation
from the Commission for operating
within the footprint of an organized
wholesale electricity market
automatically qualify for relief under
the 1 MW threshold; and (3) how
interconnection requirements would be
considered for QFs between 1 MW and
20 MWs—specifically whether these
projects would need to interconnect at
transmission level voltages to be
considered as having access to the
wholesale electricity market.946 The
Michigan Commission notes that there
is some tension between the proposal
and the market rules for MISO and
PJM.947
620. Several commenters request that
the Commission expand the exemption
for cogeneration to small power QFs
whose primary purpose is to self-supply
but still rely on PURPA when making
occasional sales to the interconnected
utility when QF output exceeds on-site
consumption.948 Industrial Energy
942 Connecticut
Commission Comments at 21–23.
River Energy Comments at 3.
944 FirstEnergy Comments at 2–3.
945 Indiana Municipal Comments at 8–9.
946 Michigan Commission Comments at 6–7
947 Id. at 7 (commenting that MISO, for example,
utilizes a 5 MW threshold as the cut off point for
Network Modeling purposes and that resources less
than 5 MW are modeled on a case-by-case basis
only).
948 ELCON Comments at 32–33; Industrial Energy
Consumers Comments at 6–8; Chamber of
Commerce Comments at 7.
943 Missouri
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
Consumers suggest that small power
producers seeking a 20 MW self-supply
exemption meet the ‘‘fundamental use
test’’ which currently applies to
cogeneration facilities.949 Other
commenters assert that behind-themeter distributed energy resources,950
Waste to Energy resources,951 and
baseload renewables 952 are similar to
cogeneration facilities and should be
included in the exemption.
621. Public Interest Organizations
request that the Commission clarify that
utilities are required to petition to
eliminate the must-purchase obligation
for small QFs, even for those utilities
that have previously made such a
showing for QFs larger than 20 MW.953
NRECA, concerned over a potential
change in aggregation for distributed
energy resources in RTOs/ISOs, requests
that the Commission clarify that the
presumption will only apply to those
facilities having sufficient transmission
access to the RTO/ISO markets.954
622. Hydropower Association asserts
that, despite their potential, hydropower
resources do not receive the same tax
treatment and eligibility for state RPSs
and therefore have not enjoyed the same
growth rate as other renewable energy
small power producers. Hydropower
Association urges the Commission to
retain the 20 MW rebuttable
presumption for hydropower resources,
as would be the case for cogenerators,
because hydropower resources are
required by the FPA section 10(a) to be
best adapted for comprehensive uses,
including non-power generation
purposes such as irrigation, flood
control, navigation, recreation,
environmental restoration, and wildlife
preservation. Hydropower Association
states that non-powered dams by
definition were not constructed to
generate power. Because power
generation is therefore a secondary use
of these facilities, Hydropower
Association asserts that subjecting these
facilities to new avoided cost
calculations will necessarily burden
hydropower resources more than other
small power production facilities.
Hydropower Association also asserts
that there is almost 5 GW of potential
non-power dams that could be
developed and that the 20 MW
949 Industrial
Energy Consumers Comments at 9–
10.
950 One
Energy Comments at 2.
Energy Consumers Comments at 9–
951 Industrial
10.
952 Renewable
Baseload Coalition Comments at 2.
Interest Organizations Comments at 76.
954 NRECA Comments at 18–19.
953 Public
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
exemption should be retained for these
resources.955
623. Ohio Consumers Counsel states
that lowering the rebuttable
presumption could permit electric
utilities and state policies to deny QFs
and distributed energy resources under
20 MW from having unrestricted and
nondiscriminatory access to wholesale
markets. For example, Ohio Consumers
Counsel states that the NOPR would
permit electric distribution utilities to
limit the availability of after-the-meter
generation and storage from PJM’s
markets, such as through restrictive net
metering requirements, unreasonably
low compensation for distributed energy
resources, or other state regulatory and
policy restrictions. Ohio Consumers
Counsel urges the Commission to
require that investor-owned electric
distribution utilities demonstrate that
they have not restricted market access to
QFs and distributed energy resources
rated between 1 MW and 20 MW.956
e. Commission Determination
624. We agree with commenters that,
in Order Nos. 688 and 688–A, given
conditions at the time, the Commission
established the rebuttable presumption
at QFs 20 MW or less. Furthermore, as
commenters noted in reviewing several
individual cases in 2013–2015, the
Commission continued to find that
those individual small power
production facilities 20 MW or less still
needed the additional protections and
encouragement.957 However, since
Order Nos. 688 and 688–A the
Commission has recognized multiple
examples of small power production
facilities under 20 MW participating in
RTO/ISO energy markets. The
Commission found that the electric
utilities in those proceedings rebutted
the presumption of no market access
and therefore terminated the mandatory
purchase obligation.958
625. We adopt the proposal to revise
18 CFR 292.309(d) to reduce the net
power production capacity level at
which the presumption of
nondiscriminatory access to a market
attaches for small power production
facilities, but not for cogeneration
facilities. However, recognizing some of
the challenges that QFs near 1 MW have
in participating in such markets that
have been identified by commenters, in
955 Hydropower Association Comments at 2–7
(citing 16 U.S.C. 803).
956 Ohio Consumers Counsel Comments at 2–5.
957 PPL Elec. Utilities Corp., 145 FERC ¶ 61,053 at
P 24; Va. Elec. & Power Co., 151 FERC ¶ 61,038, at
P 21; N. States Power Co., 151 FERC ¶ 61,110.
958 See, e.g., Fitchburg Gas and Elec. Light Co.,
146 FERC ¶ 61,186, at P 33 (2014); City of
Burlington, Vt., 145 FERC ¶ 61,121, at P 33 (2013).
PO 00000
Frm 00079
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
54715
this final rule we lower the rebuttable
presumption from 20 MW to 5 MW,
rather than from 20 MW to 1 MW as
proposed in the NOPR. Under the final
rule, small power production facilities
with a net power production capacity at
or below 5 MW will be presumed not to
have nondiscriminatory access to
markets, and, conversely, small power
production facilities with a net power
production capacity over 5 MW will be
presumed to have nondiscriminatory
access to markets.
626. A number of commenters oppose
the reduction below 20 MW, arguing the
lack of a record to support the proposal.
We disagree. In Order Nos. 688 and
688–A, the Commission determined that
small QFs may not have
nondiscriminatory access to wholesale
markets and, therefore, it was
reasonable to establish a presumption
for small QFs. At that time, the
Commission found that it was
‘‘reasonable and administratively
workable’’ to define ‘‘small’’ for
purposes of this regulation to be QFs
below 20 MW.959 We also note that a
number of commenters, including state
entities which are charged with
applying PURPA in their
jurisdictions,960 supported a reduction
in the 20 MW threshold.
627. The Commission acknowledged
that there is no unique number to draw
a line for determining what is a small
entity.961 In establishing 20 MW
presumption as the line between large
and small QFs for purposes of section
210(m), the Commission looked at other
non-QF rulemaking orders in which it
considered what was a small entity and
those orders showed 20 MW was a
reasonable number at which to draw the
line.962 But, as explained below, the
Commission has since determined,
based on changed circumstances since
the issuance of Order Nos. 688 and 688–
A, that entities with capacity lower than
20 MW have nondiscriminatory access
to the markets and, therefore, capacity
959 See Order No. 688, 117 FERC ¶ 61,078 at PP
74–78 (establishing rebuttable presumption); Order
No. 688–A, 119 FERC ¶ 61,305 at P 95 (‘‘There is
no perfect bright line that can be drawn and we
have reasonably exercised our discretion in
adopting a 20 MW or below demarcation for
purposes of determining which QFs are unlikely to
have nondiscriminatory access to markets.’’).
960 See Connecticut Commission Comments at
20–21; Kentucky Commission Comments at 8.
961 Order No. 688–A, 119 FERC ¶ 61,305 at P 97
(‘‘Although there is no unique and distinct
megawatt size that uniquely determines if a
generator is small, in other contexts the
Commission has used 20 MW, based on similar
considerations to those presented here, to
determine the applicability of its rules and
policies.’’).
962 See Order No. 688, 117 FERC ¶ 61,078 at P 76;
Order No. 688–A, 119 FERC ¶ 61,305 at PP 96–97.
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
54716
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
level of 20 MW may no longer be a
reasonable place to establish the
presumption on what constitutes a
smaller entity under our regulations.
628. Similar to our analysis in Order
No. 688, we have determined that
entities below 20 MW now can
participate in RTO/ISO markets.963
Here, we are updating the rebuttable
presumption based on industry changes
since Order No. 688. Moreover, it is
reasonable to update the rebuttable
presumption as markets defined in
PURPA section 210(m)(1)(A), (B), and
(C) evolve because that statute itself
does not establish a presumption and
we are updating the rules, as PURPA
provides we will do from time to time,
to ensure we comply with PURPA.
However, because the revised
presumption established in this final
rule is a rebuttable presumption, QFs
can seek to overcome it.
629. Over the last 15 years, the RTO/
ISO markets have matured, market
participants have gained a better
understanding of the mechanics of such
markets, and, as a result, we find that it
is reasonable to presume that access to
the RTO/ISO markets has improved and
that it is appropriate to update the
presumption for smaller production
facilities. As we did in Order No. 688,
we have looked to indicia in other
orders to determine where the
presumption should be set.
630. We find that at this time, market
rules are inclusive of power producers
below 20 MW participating in markets.
For example, since the issuance of
Order No. 688, the Commission has
required public utilities to increase the
availability of a Fast-Track
interconnection process for projects up
to 5 MW.964 That the Commission chose
a 5 MW cut-off for eligibility for the fasttrack procedures represents an implicit
judgment by the Commission that
facilities larger than 5 MW do not need
such procedures to be able to
interconnect to the grid.
631. While the existence of Fast-Track
interconnection processes does not on
its own demonstrate nondiscriminatory
access for resources under 20 MW, it
does indicate that entities smaller than
20 MW have access to the market.
Presuming that QFs above 5 MW have
such access is therefore a reasonable
approach to identifying a capacity level
at which to update the rebuttable
963 In fact, when the Commission established the
rebuttable presumption of 20 MW, commenters in
that proceeding cited instances where QFs at 1 MW
or above had already had nondiscriminatory access
to RTOs/ISOs. See Order No. 688, 117 FERC
¶ 61,078 at PP 64–66.
964 Order No. 792, 145 FERC ¶ 61,159, at P 103,
clarified, Order No. 792–A, 146 FERC ¶ 61,214.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
presumption of nondiscriminatory
market access.
632. Additionally, since the issuance
of Order No. 688 the Commission has
required each RTO/ISO to update its
tariff to include a participation model
for electric storage resources that
established a minimum size
requirement for participation in the
RTO/ISO markets that does not exceed
100 kW.965 These proposals require
RTO/ISOs to revise their tariffs to
provide easier access for smaller
resources. Requiring markets to
accommodate storage resources to as
low as 100 kW also supports that
resources smaller than 20 MW have
nondiscriminatory access to those RTO/
ISO markets. The Commission believes
that these developments support
updating the 20 MW presumption to a
lower number.
633. Commenters argue that
individually each of these changes in
circumstances, standing alone, may not
support the reduction of the threshold
below 20 MW. But when the changes
are viewed together, we find that their
cumulative effect demonstrates that it is
reasonable for the Commission to
maintain a small entity rule but update
its determination of what is a small
entity under this presumption under the
PURPA regulations. Additionally, the
prospect of increased participation of
distributed energy resources in energy
markets further supports the proposition
that wholesale markets are
accommodating resources with smaller
capacities.966
634. The Commission recognizes that
certain of these precedents would
support reducing the presumption
below 5 MW, and perhaps even lower
than 1 MW. However, the Commission
has carefully considered the comments
detailing the problems that QFs have
had in participating in RTO/ISO
markets, problems that necessarily are
more acute for smaller QFs at or near
the 1 MW threshold proposed in the
NOPR.967 The Commission therefore has
determined that a 5 MW is a more
reasonable threshold of non965 Order
No. 841, 162 FERC ¶ 61,127 at P 265.
e.g., Elec. Participation in Mkts Operated
by Reg’l Transmission Orgs and Independent Sys.
Operators, 157 FERC ¶ 61,121, P 129 (2016) (‘‘The
costs of distributed energy resources have decreased
significantly, which when paired with alternative
revenue streams and innovative financing solutions,
is increasing these resources’ potential to compete
in and deliver value to the organized wholesale
electric markets.’’ (footnote omitted)).]
967 See, e.g., Allco Comments at 17–19; Advanced
Energy Economy Comments at 10–11; DC
Commission Comments at 5; Public Interest
Organizations Comments at 89–90; SEIA Comments
at 45–49.
966 See,
PO 00000
Frm 00080
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
discriminatory access to RTO/ISO
markets.
635. Based on the foregoing, we find
it reasonable to update the presumption
under these regulations as to what
constitutes a small entity that has nondiscriminatory access to RTO/ISO
markets and markets of comparable
competitive quality below 20 MW, and
that 5 MW represents a reasonable new
threshold that accounts for the change
of circumstances indicating that 20 MW
no longer is appropriate but also
accommodates commenters’ concerns
that a 1 MW threshold would be too
low. We acknowledge that ‘‘there is no
unique and distinct megawatt size that
uniquely determines if a generator is
small.’’ 968 We find that a 5 MW
threshold accords with PURPA’s
mandate to encourage small power
production facilities, recognizes the
progress made in wholesale markets as
discussed above, and balances the
competing claims of those seeking a
lower threshold and those seeking a
higher threshold.
636. Individual small power
production QFs that are over 5 MW and
less than 20 MW can seek to make the
case, however, that they do not truly
have nondiscriminatory access to a
market and should still be entitled to a
mandatory purchase obligation.
637. Regarding Advanced Energy
Economy’s argument that the
Commission failed to sufficiently justify
its change in policy, we disagree.969 In
FCC v. Fox Television, the court stated
that, when an agency makes a change in
policy, the agency must show that there
are good reasons for the change, ‘‘[b]ut
it need not demonstrate to a court’s
satisfaction that the reasons for the new
policy are better than the reasons for the
old one; it suffices that the new policy
is permissible under the statute, that
there are good reasons for it, and that
the agency believes it to be better, which
the conscious change of course
adequately indicates.’’ 970
638. To be clear, we are maintaining
our determination from Order No. 688
that small entities potentially may not
have non-discriminatory access for
purposes of PURPA section 210(m).
However, as explained above, the
Commission has determined that using
20 MW as an indicator of what
constitutes a small entity is no longer
valid. Entities below 20 MW
increasingly have access to the markets,
become familiar with practices and
procedures, and that markets have since
968 Order
No. 688–A, 119 FERC ¶ 61,305 at P 97.
Energy Economy Comments at 6
(citing FCC v. Fox Television, 556 U.S. at 515).
970 FCC v. Fox Television, 556 U.S. at 515.
969 Advanced
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
implemented several changes to provide
easier access to smaller facilities,
including small power production QFs,
storage facilities, and distributed energy
resources. These changes demonstrate a
change in facts since the time we issued
Order No. 688 which supports our
updating of what constitutes a small
entity for purposes of PURPA section
210(m).
639. Accordingly, we decline to adopt
Ohio Consumers Counsel’s suggestion
that electric utilities continue to have
the burden to demonstrate that certain
small power production QFs under 20
MW have nondiscriminatory access to
markets like PJM before being relieved
of the mandatory purchase obligation
for such QFs.
640. While we find that it is
reasonable to update the rebuttable
presumption from 20 MW to 5 MW, we
recognize commenters’ concerns
regarding specific barriers to
participation in RTO markets that may
affect the nondiscriminatory access to
those markets of some individual small
power production facilities between 5
MW and 20 MW.
To address these concerns, we
additionally are revising 18 CFR
292.309(c)(2)(i)–(vi) to include factors
that small power production facilities
between 5 MW and 20 MW can point to
in seeking to rebut the presumption that
they have nondiscriminatory access.
These factors are in addition to the
existing ability, pursuant to 18 CFR
292.309(c), to rebut the presumption of
access to the market by demonstrating,
inter alia, operational characteristics or
transmission constraints.
641. Specifically, the Commission
adds to 18 CFR 292.309(c) the following
five factors: (1) Specific barriers to
connecting to the interstate transmission
grid, such as excessively high costs and
pancaked delivery rates; (2) the unique
circumstances impacting the time/
length of interconnection studies/queue
to process small power QF
interconnection requests; (3) a lack of
affiliation with entities that participate
in RTO/ISO markets; (4) a predominant
purpose other than selling electricity
which would warrant the small power
QF being treated similarly to
cogenerators (e.g., municipal solid waste
facilities, biogas facilities, run-of-river
hydro facilities, and non-powered
dams); (5) the QF has certain
operational characteristics that
effectively prevent the qualifying
facility’s participation in a market; and
(6) the QF lacks access to markets due
to transmission constraints, including
that it is located in an area where
persistent transmission constraints in
effect cause the QF not to have access
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
to markets outside a persistently
congested area to sell the QF output or
capacity. This is not intended to be an
exhaustive list of the factors that a QF
could rely upon in seeking to rebut the
presumption. These factors, among
other indicia of lack of
nondiscriminatory access, will be
assessed by the Commission on a caseby-case basis in considering a claim that
the presumption of nondiscriminatory
access to the defined markets should be
considered rebutted for a specific QF.
642. The addition of these factors
addresses commenters’ concern that not
all small power production facilities
between 5 and 20 MW may have
nondiscriminatory access to competitive
markets, and facilitates the ability of
small power production facilities facing
barriers to participation in RTO markets
to demonstrate their lack of access. For
example, while a small power
production facility between 5 MW and
20 MW does not need to be physically
interconnected to transmission facilities
to be considered as having access to the
statutorily-defined wholesale electricity
markets, we recognize there are some
small power production facilities
between 5 MW and 20 MW that may
face additional barriers, such as
excessively high costs and pancaked
delivery rates, to access wholesale
markets.
643. For example, several commenters
express concern over the resources or
administrative burden for some small
power QFs that lack the necessary
experience or expertise to participate in
energy markets. Recognizing these
concerns, we have added consideration
of both the fact that some small power
production facilities will face additional
difficulties due to costs, administrative
burdens, length of the interconnection
study process and the size of the
queues, and the fact that some small
power production QFs do not have
access to the expertise of affiliated
entities.
644. We agree with commenters that
some small power production facilities
are similar to cogeneration facilities
because their predominant purpose is
not power production. Like
cogeneration facilities, the sale of
electricity from these small power
production facilities is a byproduct of
another purpose and these facilities
might not be as familiar with energy
markets and the technical requirements
for such sales. Therefore, we will allow
the small subset of small power
production facilities that are between 20
MW and 5 MW to rebut the
presumption of access to markets where
the predominant purpose of the facility
is other than selling electricity, and the
PO 00000
Frm 00081
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
54717
sale of electricity is simply a byproduct
of that purpose. Finally, like all QFs
over 20 MW, we recognize that there
may be particular small power
production facilities with certain
operational characteristics or that are
located in an area where persistent
transmission constraints in effect cause
the QF not to have access to markets
outside a persistently congested area to
sell the QF output or capacity.
645. While we appreciate Indiana
Municipals’ concern over preserving
Commission resources, we will deny its
request to automatically apply the lower
threshold to utilities that have already
been granted termination for QFs over
the 20 MW threshold. We find that it is
appropriate to require utilities that were
previously granted termination of the
mandatory purchase obligation for new
contracts and obligations for QFs above
20 MW, but are now seeking to
terminate the mandatory purchase
obligation for new contracts and
obligations for small power production
facilities between 5 and 20 MW to
follow the procedures in 18 CFR
292.310, including procedures for
providing notice to those potentially
affected QFs within their footprint. That
is, those utilities for which the
Commission has already granted relief
from the mandatory purchase obligation
for small power production facilities
over 20 MW must reapply with the
Commission requesting relief from the
mandatory purchase obligation for small
power production facilities between 5
MW and 20 MW.
646. Among other factors, the
regulation’s notice provision mentioned
above will allow small power
production facilities between 5 MW and
20 MW an opportunity, if applicable, to
present evidence that their facility does
not have nondiscriminatory access to
defined markets based on the factors
discussed above.971 In the proceeding in
which the utility seeks to terminate the
mandatory purchase obligation between
5 MW and 20 MW, we will not entertain
arguments that the utility should lose its
previously granted termination of
purchase obligation at 20 MW and
above; our regulations provide how a
mandatory purchase obligation can be
reinstated. We do not, in this final rule,
change a QF’s right to seek
reinstatement of the mandatory
purchase obligation where the
conditions set forth in 18 CFR
292.309(a), (b), or (c) are no longer
met.972
647. Regarding the Michigan
Commission’s questions, this final rule
971 18
CFR 292.310.
18 CFR 292.311.
972 See
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
54718
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
preserves the rights or remedies of any
party under existing contracts or
obligations, in effect or pending
approval before the appropriate state
regulatory authority or non-regulated
electric utility on or before December
31, 2020 with QFs between 5 MW and
20 MW. Consistent with Commission
precedent, this final rule defines the
term ‘‘obligations’’ broadly to
encompass any existing legally
enforceable obligation.973
2. Reliance on RFPs and Liquid Market
Hubs To Terminate Purchase Obligation
Under PURPA Section 210(m)
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
a. NOPR Discussion
648. In the NOPR, the Commission
noted that NARUC had proposed that
the Commission allow utilities to rely
on RFPs (in combination with liquid
market hubs) to establish eligibility to
terminate a utility’s purchase obligation
pursuant to PURPA section
210(m)(1)(C).974 After describing
generally how such a proposal might be
structured, NARUC suggested that ‘‘[t]he
Commission should create a yardstick of
characteristics that describe in detail
how a utility could qualify for an
exemption under subparagraph (C).’’ 975
649. The Commission stated that,
under the PURPA Regulations, electric
utilities already may seek to terminate
their mandatory purchase obligation
pursuant to PURPA section 210(m)(1)(C)
by demonstrating that a particular
market is of comparable competitive
quality to markets described in PURPA
section 210(m)(1)(A) and (B).976 The
973 See Cedar Creek Wind LLC, 137 FERC
¶ 61,006, at PP 35–36 n.62 (2011) (stating that
courts have recognized negotiations regarding terms
that parties to the negotiations intend to become
finalized or written contract, may in some
circumstances result in legally enforceable
obligations on those parties notwithstanding the
absence of a writing). See generally Burbach
Broadcasting Co. of Delaware v. Elkins Radio Corp.,
278 F.3d 401, 407–09 (4th Cir. 2002); Adjustrite
Systems, Inc. v. GAB Business Serv., Inc., 145 F.3d
543, 550 (2d Cir. 1998); Miller Constr. Co. v.
Stresstek, 697 P.2d 1201, 1202–04 (Idaho 1985).);
see also JD Wind 1, LLC, 129 FERC ¶ 61,148 at P
25; Grouse Creek Wind Park, LLC, 142 FERC
¶ 61,187 at PP 40–41.
974 NOPR, 168 FERC ¶ 61,184 at P 131 (citing
NARUC Supplemental Comments, Docket No.
AD16–16–000 (filed Oct. 17, 2018)).
975 Id., attach. A at 9.
976 Id. P 132 (citing Order No. 688–A, 119 FERC
¶ 61,305 at P 43 (‘‘Congress believed the two types
of markets identified in subparagraphs (A) and (B),
while distinct between themselves, contain certain
competitive qualities that justify termination of the
purchase requirement for any QF with
nondiscriminatory access to those markets.
Subparagraph (C) directs the Commission to
consider these competitive qualities when
analyzing whether there are other markets that,
while not meeting the specific requirements of
subparagraphs (A) and (B), are sufficiently
competitive to justify termination of the purchase
requirement.’’)); cf. Pub. Serv. Co. of N.M., 140
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
Commission further noted that the
current PURPA Regulations are not
prescriptive about how an electric
utility must make such a demonstration
and nothing in the PURPA Regulations
or precedent would bar an electric
utility from arguing that RFPs in
combination with liquid market hubs
are sufficient to satisfy PURPA section
210(m)(1)(C).
650. The Commission then stated that
it believed that a properly structured
proposal along the lines proposed by
NARUC potentially could satisfy the
statutory requirements under PURPA
section 210(m)(1)(C) and that it would
consider such proposals on a case-bycase basis. Although the Commission
did not propose additional criteria a
utility or utilities may rely on to satisfy
PURPA section 210(m)(1)(C), the
Commission sought comments on any
specific factors that would be useful to
consider in determining how a utility or
utilities may satisfy PURPA section
210(m)(1)(C).977
b. Comments
i. Comments in Opposition
651. A few commenters do not
support allowing competition to be an
alternative to the mandatory purchase
obligation.978 ELCON is concerned that
no state competitive procurement is
robust enough to replace avoided
capacity costs.979 Solar Energy
Industries supports using RFPs to set
avoided cost rates, but does not support
using RFPs to vitiate utilities’
mandatory purchase obligations.980
652. Public Interest Organizations
contend that RFPs are not comparable in
quality to PURPA section 210(m)(1)(A)
or (B) markets because there is only a
single buyer and there are no safeguards
against the anti-competitive behavior of
that buyer, such as favoring its own or
an affiliate’s generation.981 NIPPC,
CREA, REC, and OSEIA state that, while
they agree in principle that competition
should be the motivating force in energy
markets, their experience shows that
FERC ¶ 61,191, at PP 29–38 (2012) (denying
application to terminate mandatory purchase
obligation on the grounds that the Four Corners
Hub is not of comparable competitive quality to
markets in sections 210(m)(1)(A) and (B) of
PURPA)).
977 Id. P 133.
978 Allco Comments at 17–19; Public Interest
Organizations Comments at 90.
979 ELCON Comments at 19.
980 Solar Energy Industries Comments at 24
(citing Solar Energy Industries, Supplemental
Comments, Docket No. AD16–16–000, at 10–37, 40–
58 (filed Aug. 28, 2019)).
981 Public Interest Organizations Comments at 93.
PO 00000
Frm 00082
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
utility-sponsored RFP programs often
fall far short of genuine competition.982
653. Public Interest Organizations
state that Order No. 688–A specifies that
demonstrating that a market offers ‘‘a
meaningful opportunity to sell’’ usually
requires evidence of QF transactions,
which is not possible with a market
hub.983 Public Interest Organizations
argue that market hubs are not
equivalent to PURPA section
210(m)(1)(A) or (B) markets because,
unlike an independently administered
auction, there is no guarantee that a QF
will be able to sell their energy even if
it is the lowest cost resource.984
654. Public Interest Organizations
further contend that the Commission
does not have the authority to approve
RFPs or liquid market hubs as PURPA
section 210(m)(1)(C) wholesale markets
because they are not of comparable
qualify to Day 1 or Day 2 markets, i.e.,
to PURPA section 210(a)(1)(A) or (B)
markets.985
ii. Comments in Support
655. Several commenters support
allowing competition to be an
alternative to the mandatory purchase
obligation.986 ELCON supports
competitive procurements that exempt
industrial self-supply.987
656. APPA supports the Commission
reviewing factors that would determine
if a market is competitive and
comparable to PURPA sections
210(m)(1)(A) and (B).988 Xcel proposes
that the PURPA section 210(m)(1)(C)
test should evaluate whether market
players have a reasonable opportunity to
participate in the market, rather than
whether the type of market is similar to
PURPA section 210(m)(1)(A) and (B)
markets.989 A few commenters
requested a technical conference to
identify the criteria for determining
what processes are competitive.990
Colorado Independent Energy would
like the RFP standard for PURPA
section 210(m)(1)(C) status to be higher
than for QF pricing and include
evaluation of bid data and the modeling
process to show the absence of bias
against renewable and cogeneration
982 NIPPC,
CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at
66.
983 Public Interest Organizations Comments at 92
(citing Order No. 688–A, 119 FERC ¶ 61,305 at P
38).
984 Id.
985 Id. at 90–91.
986 Advanced Energy Economy Comments at 12;
APPA Comments at 29; Colorado Independent
Energy Comments at 7; Xcel Comments at 11.
987 ELCON Comments at 19.
988 APPA Comments at 26–29.
989 Xcel Comments at 11.
990 Advanced Energy Economy Comments at 13;
ELCON Comments at 19.
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
projects and likewise the absence of bias
for utility self-build projects.991
657. Arizona Public Service agrees
with NARUC that the Commission
should allow utilities to rely on RFPs to
establish eligibility to terminate the
utility’s purchase obligation pursuant to
PURPA section 210(m)(1)(C). Arizona
Public Service believes this proposal is
one way a utility could demonstrate that
a market is of comparable competitive
quality to the markets described in
PURPA sections 210(m)(1)(A) and
(B).992
658. APPA argues that market hubs
should be considered as possibly
comparable, particularly to PURPA
section 210(m)(1)(B), which requires
that QFs have access to Commissionapproved transmission service and
competitive wholesale markets for long
and short-term capacity and energy
sales.993 APPA highlights the
Commission finding that the MidColumbia and Palo Verde hubs have
sufficient liquidity to find just and
reasonable rates and adds that an
empirical test of market liquidity could
be created.994
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
c. Commission Determination
659. In this final rule, we affirm that
we will consider utility proposals to
terminate the purchase obligation
pursuant to PURPA section 210(m)(1)(C)
on a case-by-case basis, including utility
proposals based on competitive
solicitations or liquid market hubs.
660. In response to Public Interest
Organizations, as explained above in
Section IV.A.1, PURPA section 210(m)
obligates the Commission to grant any
request to terminate a utility’s obligation
to purchase from a QF with
nondiscriminatory access to the
specified markets that satisfy that
provision. Whether any particular
market is of comparable quality to a Day
1 or Day 2 market necessarily must be
determined in the context of an
individual case.
661. We refrain from outlining here an
exhaustive list of factors that will be
used in any such case-by-case
evaluation, but at a minimum we will be
guided by the important criteria
discussed previously in this rule in
section IV.B.8 on the use of competitive
solicitations to determine avoided costs.
662. Consistent with our findings and
discussion in section IV.B.4 on the use
of market hubs to determine avoided
cost, the Commission finds that
991 Colorado Independent Energy Comments at 6,
11–12.
992 Arizona Public Service Comments at 8–10.
993 APPA Comments at 27.
994 Id. at 28.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
54719
competitive market prices in general
should reflect the avoided cost energy
rates of utilities with access to such
markets in a given region. We will
therefore consider, on a case-by-case
basis, whether a properly run RFP or
competitive acquisition process may
also justify termination of the PURPA
purchase obligation pursuant to PURPA
section 210(m)(1)(C).
reliably plan their systems while
ensuring resource adequacy.
Additionally, the development and
definition of objective and reasonable
factors to determine commercial
viability and financial commitment to
construct a facility would encourage the
development of QFs by providing QFs
with more certainty as to when they will
obtain a LEO.995
H. Legally Enforceable Obligation
2. Comments
1. NOPR Proposal
663. The Commission proposed to
add regulatory text in 18 CFR
292.304(d)(3) to require QFs to
demonstrate that a proposed project is
commercially viable and that the QF has
a financial commitment to construct the
proposed project pursuant to objective,
reasonable, state-determined criteria in
order to be eligible for a LEO. The
Commission further proposed to
provide that states have flexibility as to
what constitutes an acceptable showing
of commercial viability and financial
commitment.
664. The Commission stated that its
objective in requiring a showing of
commercial viability and the QF’s
financial commitment to construct the
project was to ensure that no electric
utility obligation is triggered for those
QF projects that are not sufficiently
advanced in their development and,
therefore, for which it would be
unreasonable for a utility to include in
its resource planning, while at the same
time ensuring that the purchasing utility
does not unilaterally and unreasonably
decide when its obligation arises. The
NOPR proposed that states may require
a showing, for example, that a QF has
satisfied, or is in the process of
undertaking, at least some of the
following prerequisites: (1) Obtaining
site control adequate to commence
construction of the project at the
proposed location; (2) filing an
interconnection application with the
appropriate entity; (3) securing local
permitting and zoning; or (4) other
similar, objective, reasonable criteria
that allow a QF to demonstrate its
commercial viability and financial
commitment to construct the facilities.
The NOPR stated that these proposed
indicia were not intended to be
exhaustive and the Commission sought
comment on these indicia and others
that also might be appropriate for
consideration.
665. The Commission stated that it
believed requiring QFs to demonstrate
their commercial viability and financial
commitment to construct the facilities
based on such indicia before obtaining
a LEO would allow electric utilities to
a. Comments in Opposition
PO 00000
Frm 00083
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
666. Several commenters oppose the
Commission’s proposal to require QFs
to demonstrate that a proposed project
is commercially viable and the QF has
a financial commitment to construct the
proposed project pursuant to objective,
reasonable, state-determined criteria in
order to be eligible for a LEO and that
states have flexibility as to what
constitutes an acceptable showing of
commercial viability and financial
commitment, arguing it undermines
PURPA’s intent to promote QF
development.996
667. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA
argue that developers cannot obtain
financing without the financial
commitment of a PPA or LEO from the
utility and therefore requiring financial
viability as a condition precedent to
obtain a LEO is problematic.997 Western
Resource Councils argues that the NOPR
proposal represents an onerous financial
and bureaucratic barrier that will lead to
a substantial reduction in the number of
QFs.998
668. Southeast Public Interest
Organizations argue that the proposal
does not sufficiently narrow the range of
divergent LEO tests that have already
been adopted by the states and opposes
allowing states additional flexibility in
establishing criteria up to a fully
executed agreement.999 sPower requests
that the Commission establish specific
criteria and prohibit states from
imposing any additional criteria.1000
Solar Energy Industries requests that the
Commission develop a concrete baseline
995 Because QFs already in operation have
necessarily demonstrated a commitment to
construct the project, the Commission stated that it
does not intend commercial viability and financial
commitment requirements to serve as prerequisites
to QFs already in operation with existing LEOs to
obtaining new LEOs.
996 NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at
81; Public Interest Organizations Comments at 98;
Western Resource Councils Comments at 144.
997 NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at
81.
998 Western Resource Councils Comments at 144.
999 Southeast Public Interest Organizations
Comments at 43
1000 sPower Comments at 14.
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
54720
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
in determining when a QF is entitled to
a purchase contract.
669. Solar Energy Industries and
Public Interest Organizations argue that
requiring developers to invest
additional capital prior to obtaining a
LEO will prevent smaller companies
who are unable to invest heavily in
early state development activity from
participating.1001 Solar Energy
Industries argue that it is unjust and
unreasonable to require QFs to invest
millions of dollars in site control,
permit acquisition and interconnection
costs in order to secure the opportunity
to negotiate with the purchasing utility.
For those states that do not willingly
disclose their avoided cost rates or
methodology, the NOPR’s LEO proposal
requires QFs to incur substantial
expense to establish their commercial
viability without a reasonable
understanding of what their rate may
be.1002
670. In striking a balance between
interconnection and development risk,
Solar Energy Industries proposes that
the first prerequisite to a LEO formation
be either: (a) The completion of the
System Impact Study (or the equivalent
in the state interconnection process); or
(b) where the utility cannot complete
the System Impact Study within a
reasonable period of time, one year after
tendering an interconnection request to
the host utility.1003 Where a QF has
obtained site control, initiated state
permitting processes, submitted an
interconnection request and associated
study deposit, and has been certified
through the submission of a Form No.
556, the Commission should find that
the QF is eligible to establish a LEO to
sell to the purchasing utility, provided
that: (1) The QF has received a System
Impact Study report (or equivalent) or
one year has elapsed since the QF’s
interconnection request was tendered to
the host utility; and (2) the QF commits
to achieving commercial operation
within 180 days of the completion of all
interconnection facilities and network
upgrades by the utility.1004 Solar Energy
Industries asserts that QFs would, upon
satisfaction of these criteria, be legally
entitled to negotiate with the purchasing
utility to develop a PPA setting forth the
terms and conditions of the purchase,
including liability if the QF fails to
perform. Projects that reach agreement
will proceed according to the terms of
the PPA and the purchasing utility can
establish milestones with enough
1001 Solar Energy Industries Comments at 41;
Public Interest Organization Comments at 80–82.
1002 Solar Energy Industries Comments at 41.
1003 Id. at 43.
1004 Id.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
financial protection to ensure that
ratepayers will not be harmed if the QF
fails to begin operations.1005
671. American Dams argues that
Interconnection Agreements are
generally processed far too slowly, a
problem that should be addressed by the
Commission.1006
672. Southeast Public Interest
Organizations support the requirement
of demonstrating site control, but state
that requiring permits can be timeconsuming and costly such that prefinancing QFs may not have the
resources for the lengthy permitting
process, and it is unreasonable to expect
a QF to incur these expenses until it has
secured a price for its output so that it
can in turn secure financing for the
project.1007
b. Comments in Support
673. Numerous commenters support
the NOPR’s LEO proposal, asserting that
state agencies are better positioned to
develop criteria that reflect their unique
operational circumstances, resource
planning needs and risk appetite.1008
Several commenters note that the
proposed factors provide a reasonable
balance between the planning needs of
the connecting utility and certainty to
QF developers.1009 Several commenters
assert that requiring QFs to demonstrate
commercial viability and financial
commitment will reduce the reliability
or other risks a utility faces by having
to plan for its system needs or resource
adequacy around a QF that is never
developed.1010
674. Several commenters agree that
the proposed regulations will provide
certainty to host utilities and state
commissions while decreasing systems
impact and associated costs.1011
1005 Id.
1006 American
Dams Comments at 5–6.
Public Interest Organization
Comments at 43–44.
1008 Alaska Power Comments at 1–2; APPA
Comments at 30; Chamber of Commerce at 8;
Colorado Independent Energy Comments at 13;
Connecticut Authority Comments at 24–25;
Consumer Alliance Comments at 2; Consumers
Energy Comments at 5; East Kentucky Comments at
3–4; East River at 2; El Paso Electric Comments at
6–7; Golden Valley Comments at 7–8; Indiana
Municipal Comments at 11–12; Institute for Energy
Research Comments at 2; Massachusetts DPU
Comments at 10; NARUC Comments at 7–8; NIPPC,
CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 81; NRECA
Comments at 21; North Carolina Commission Staff
Comments at 6; Northern Laramie Range Alliance
Comments at 3–4; Ohio Commission Energy
Advocate Comments at 10; Oregon Commission at
6.
1009 Alliant Energy Comments at 21; Industrial
Energy Consumers Comments at 14–16.
1010 Duke Energy Comments at 19; EEI Comments
at 37.
1011 Alliant Energy Comments at 21–22; NRECA
at 21; Northern Laramie Range Alliance Comments
at 3–4.
1007 Southeast
PO 00000
Frm 00084
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
675. Connecticut Authority supports
the proposal arguing that the factors
included in the NOPR will provide
greater certainty and less risk to QF
developers and purchasing utilities
which is consistent with PURPA’s goal
of developing renewable resources.1012
The Chamber of Commerce argues that
the proposed factors indicate a
developer’s good-faith intention to
ultimately develop its proposed QF.1013
The Michigan Commission states that it
supports the proposal, currently has a
rulemaking and several cases pending
regarding LEOs, and appreciates any
additional clarity the Commission could
provide.1014
c. Comments Requesting Modification
676. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA
request that the Commission: (1) Further
define the terms ‘‘commercial viability’’
and ‘‘financial commitment’’ to avoid
litigation; (2) clarify that any changes to
the LEO rules will not affect the
viability of any executed contract
between a developer and utility,
regardless of the facility’s development
status; and (3) clarify that the LEO rules
will not preclude nor bar any utility
from executing a PPA before the QF may
be able to demonstrate compliance with
the implementation of LEO rules.1015
i. Studies
677. NorthWestern requests that the
Commission require more than just the
submission of an interconnection
application prior to obtaining a LEO in
order to demonstrate that the proposal
is more than a speculative paper
project.1016 Portland General requests
that the Commission allow states to
require developers to have completed
the first interconnection study.1017 The
South Dakota Commission states that
developers should be required to have
completed a transmission feasibility
study or system impact study with a
determination of the interconnection
costs the QF would be required to pay
prior to obtaining a LEO.1018 Portland
General requests that off-system QFs be
required to have completed the first
study milestone of the transmission
service request.1019
678. SC Solar Alliance requests that
the Commission adopt a recent South
Carolina Commission ruling that a QF
should be able to establish a LEO after
1012 Connecticut
Authority Comments at 24–25.
of Commerce Comments at 8.
1014 Michigan Commission Comments at 7–8.
1015 NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at
81–83.
1016 NorthWestern Comments at 15–16.
1017 Portland General Comments at 20.
1018 South Dakota Commission Comments at 2.
1019 Portland General Comments at 20.
1013 Chamber
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
receiving a System Impact Study or
within one year if a System Impact
Study is not provided in a timely
manner and that PPA in-service dates
must be extended based on
interconnection delays.1020
to reject purchases from QFs if the
utility has no need for additional
capacity. The Institute for Energy
Research states that such need could be
determined separately, on an annual
basis, a stand-alone basis, or as part of
an IRP process.1028
ii. Commercial Viability
679. Alliant Energy requests that the
Commission consider requiring QF
developers to have contracts in place
with equipment suppliers and an
analysis of interconnections needed.1021
680. North Carolina Commission Staff
requests that the Commission adopt a
North Carolina Commission standard
that QFs must (1) commit to sell their
power via a written notice of
commitment by the earlier of 105 days
after submission of an interconnection
request or upon receipt of the system
impact study, (2) have filed a report of
proposed construction, and (3)
submitted an interconnection request
under the state’s interconnection
protocol which requires the QF to
demonstrate site control.1022 sPower
argues that option contracts should be
sufficient to demonstrate site
control.1023
iii. Financial Viability
681. Portland General and sPower
suggest requiring developers to pay a
deposit to state commissions to
demonstrate financial viability with the
amount based on the capacity of the QF
and released upon project
completion.1024 Portland General asserts
that having to post a deposit encourages
developers to perform sufficient due
diligence prior to claiming a LEO.1025
682. North Carolina Commission Staff
argues that, in order to protect
ratepayers from QFs gaming the process,
any project that backs out of its notice
of commitment should only receive asavailable rates for two years.1026
iv. Rejecting QF Purchases and
Expanded Curtailment Rights
683. North Carolina Commission Staff
suggests that the Commission update its
regulations to allow curtailing QFs
when it would be uneconomic for the
utility to make such purchases.1027 The
Institute for Energy Research argues that
the Commission should allow a utility
1020 SC
Solar Alliance Comments at 15.
Energy Comments at 22.
1022 North Carolina Commission Staff Comments
at 6.
1023 sPower Comments at 15.
1024 Portland General Comments at 15–16; sPower
Comments at 14–15.
1025 Portland General Comments at 20–21.
1026 North Carolina Commission Staff Comments
at 6.
1027 Id. at 8.
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
1021 Alliant
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
3. Commission Determination
684. In this final rule, we adopt the
NOPR proposal to require QFs to
demonstrate that a proposed project is
commercially viable and that the QF has
a financial commitment to construct the
proposed project, pursuant to objective,
reasonable, state-determined criteria in
order to be eligible for a LEO.1029 We
also affirm that the states have
flexibility as to what constitutes an
acceptable showing of commercial
viability and financial commitment,
albeit subject to the criteria being
objective and reasonable. We find that
requiring a showing of commercial
viability and financial commitment,
based on objective and reasonable
criteria, will ensure that no electric
utility obligation is triggered for those
QF projects that are not sufficiently
advanced in their development, and
therefore, for which it would be
unreasonable for a utility to include in
its resource planning. At the same time,
the criteria ensure that the purchasing
utility does not unilaterally and
unreasonably decide when its obligation
arises. We believe this strikes the right
balance for QF developers and
purchasing utilities and should
encourage development of QFs.
685. Examples of factors a state could
reasonably require are that a QF
demonstrate that it is in the process of
at least some of the following
prerequisites: (1) Taking meaningful
steps to obtain site control adequate to
commence construction of the project at
the proposed location and (2) filing an
interconnection application with the
appropriate entity. The state could also
require that the QF show that it has
submitted all applications, including
filing fees, to obtain all necessary local
permitting and zoning approvals. We
note that the factors that the state
requires must be factors that are within
the control of the QF. Thus, we clarify
that it is appropriate for states to require
a QF to demonstrate that it is in the
process of obtaining site control or has
applied for all local permitting and
zoning approvals, rather than requiring
a QF to show that it has obtained site
control or secured local permitting and
zoning.
1028 Institute
for Energy Research Comments at
2–3.
1029 NOPR,
PO 00000
168 FERC ¶ 61,184 at P 140.
Frm 00085
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
54721
686. We agree with Southeast Public
Interest Organizations’ concerns
regarding requiring QFs to obtain
permits in order to determine
commercial viability. In some regions
the permitting and zoning process can
be lengthy and expensive, making
obtaining the permits and zoning
changes a condition to a LEO
unreasonable. Therefore, instead of
requiring a QF to have secured local
permitting and zoning, states can
require QFs to have applied for all of the
necessary permits and zoning variances,
including the payment of all necessary
fees, as a factor in demonstrating the
QF’s commercial viability. States may
require a showing that such applications
have been submitted to the relevant
regulatory bodies (including payment of
the application fees).
687. Several commenters argue that
requiring QFs to demonstrate financial
viability prior to obtaining a LEO is
problematic because QFs need a LEO to
obtain financing.1030 However,
demonstrating the required financial
commitment does not require a
demonstration of having obtained
financing. Requiring QFs to, for
example, apply for all relevant permits,
take meaningful steps to seek site
control, or meet other objective and
reasonable milestones in the QF’s
development can sufficiently
demonstrate QF developers’ financial
commitment in the QF development
and allows utilities to reasonably rely
on the LEO in planning for system
resource adequacy. Obtaining a PPA or
financing cannot be required to show
proof of financial commitment.
688. The intent of these factors is to
provide a reasonable balance between
providing QFs with objective and
transparent milestones up front that are
needed to obtain a LEO, allowing states
the flexibility to establish factors that
address the individual circumstances of
each state, and increasing utilities’
ability to accurately plan their
systems.1031 Establishing objective and
reasonable factors is intended to limit
the number of unviable QFs obtaining
LEOs and unnecessarily burdening
utilities that currently have to plan for
QFs that obtain a LEO very early in the
process but ultimately are never
developed.1032 In adopting this
provision, the Commission is raising the
bar to prevent speculative QFs from
obtaining LEOs, and the associated
burden on purchasing utilities, but is
1030 NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at
81; Western Resource Council Comments at 144.
1031 Alliant Energy Comments at 21; Industrial
Energy Consumers Comments at 14–16.
1032 Duke Energy Comments at 19; EEI Comments
at 37.
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
54722
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
not establishing a barrier for financially
committed developers seeking to
develop commercially viable QFs.
689. We disagree that establishing
reasonable, transparent factors is an
onerous barrier or will cause a
substantial reduction of QFs. The
objective and reasonable criteria we
have established will protect QFs
against onerous requirements for a LEO
that hinder financing, such as a
requirement for a utility’s execution of
an interconnection agreement 1033 or
power purchase agreement,1034 or
requiring that QFs file a formal
complaint with the state
commission,1035 or limiting LEOs to
only those QFs capable of supplying
firm power,1036 or requiring the QF to
be able to deliver power in 90 days.1037
We find that, by making clear that such
conditions are not permitted, and by
providing objective criteria to clarify
when a LEO commences, the LEO
provisions we have adopted will
encourage the development of QFs.
690. For those commenters that
requested that the Commission establish
specific factors for the states to apply, or
to establish a baseline for eligible
factors, or to otherwise limit states’
flexibility, we decline to do so. Since its
inception, the Commission’s PURPA
Regulations have established rules and
defined boundaries allowing states
flexibility within those boundaries in
implementing PURPA as appropriate for
each state. As commenters noted, this
allows states to address their unique
circumstances and best address each
states’ needs. Furthermore, existing
precedent establishes a baseline 1038 and
this final rule’s requirement that states
adopt objective and reasonable criteria
for determining when a QF has obtained
a LEO provides additional safeguards
(in addition to that baseline) applicable
to both QFs and utilities. Similarly,
regarding Solar Energy Industries’
proposed pre-requisites and factors, for
1033 See, e.g., FLS Energy, Inc., 157 FERC
¶ 61,211, at P 26 (2016) (FLS) (stating that requiring
signed interconnection agreement as prerequisite to
LEO is inconsistent with PURPA Regulations).
1034 See, e.g., Murphy Flat Power, LLC, 141 FERC
¶ 61,145, at P 24 (2012) (finding that requiring a
signed and executed contract with an electric utility
as a prerequisite to a LEO is inconsistent with
PURPA Regulations.
1035 See, e.g., Grouse Creek Wind Park, LLC, 142
FERC ¶ 61,187, at P 40 (2013).
1036 Exelon Wind 1, L.L.C. v. Nelson, 766 F.3d
380, 400 (5th Cir. 2014).
1037 Power Resource Group, Inc. v. Public Utility
Com’n of Texas, 422 F.3d 231, (5th Cir. 2005).
1038 For example, the Commission has held that
requiring a fully-executed contract or executed
interconnection agreement as a condition precedent
to obtaining a LEO is inconsistent with PURPA. See
FLS, 157 FERC ¶ 61,211 at P 26; Cedar Creek Wind
LLC, 137 FERC ¶ 61,006 at P 35.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
the reasons stated above, we find that
states are in the best position to
determine what specific factors would
best suit the specific circumstances of
that state, so long as they are objective
and reasonable, and we provide the
suggested prerequisites above as
examples of objective and reasonable
factors.1039 While Solar Energy
Industries’ proposed criteria may be
reasonable, we decline to mandate
specific terms for the entire country.
691. Contrary to Solar Energy
Industries’ assertions, nothing in this
final rule limits a QF developer’s or
utility’s ability to negotiate rates, terms
or conditions.1040
692. With regard to the argument that
the NOPR’s LEO proposal is
unreasonable in states that do not
disclose their avoided cost rate because
it would require QFs to incur
substantial expense to establish
commercial viability without a
reasonable understanding of the
purchase rate, we find that such statespecific implementation issues can be
addressed case-by-case. To the extent
that entities believe that a particular
state’s avoided cost rates or rate setting
methodologies do not provide sufficient
transparency to support a QF’s ability to
make reasonable commercial viability
investment decisions, such entities
could file a petition for enforcement
against the state at the Commission and,
if the Commission declines to act, later
file a petition against the state in U.S.
district court (pursuant to PURPA
section 210(h)(2)(B)).
693. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA
request that we further define the terms
commercial viability and financial
commitment. We decline. As discussed
above, we believe the best course is to
allow states the flexibility (employing
objective and reasonable factors) to
determine what constitutes commercial
viability and financial commitment
relative to the unique conditions or
circumstances in each state but also
recognizing that existing Commission
precedent establishes boundaries of
what would be considered reasonable
and not discriminatory limits for
requirements in establishing a LEO.1041
694. Additionally, we clarify that any
changes to the LEO rules adopted herein
do not affect the viability of any
executed contract or LEO between a QF
developer and utility in place as of the
effective date of this final rule,
regardless of the facility’s development
status. Further we clarify that nothing in
1039 See
supra P 685.
18 CFR 292.301(b).
1041 See FLS, 157 FERC ¶ 61,211 at P 26; Cedar
Creek Wind LLC, 137 FERC ¶ 61,006 at P 35.
1040 See
PO 00000
Frm 00086
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
the LEO rules adopted herein precludes
any utility from choosing to execute a
PPA before a QF has demonstrated
compliance with the LEO rules adopted
here.
Several commenters requested that
the Commission require QFs to do more
than just file an interconnection
application; instead, for example,
suggesting requiring completion of
system impact study, interconnection or
transmission feasibility study.1042 We
disagree. The approach taken here
recognizes the need for a QF to
demonstrate that its project is more than
mere speculation, such that it is
reasonable for a utility to consider the
resource in its planning projections. A
QF that has submitted an application for
interconnection, as well as having taken
meaningful steps to obtain site control
and has applied for all relevant permits,
while not a guarantee that the project
will be completed, are all objective and
reasonable indicators that the QF
developer is seriously pursuing the
project and has spent time and
resources in developing the project to
show a financial commitment. As
numerous commenters have explained,
QFs need a LEO in order to obtain
financing to complete the project, and
we find that, as an illustrative example,
requiring the submission of an
interconnection request (as opposed to
the completion of a system impact study
or transmission feasibility study) as one
criteria strikes an appropriate balance
between the competing needs.
695. Moreover, it bears remembering
that the concept of a LEO was
specifically adopted to prevent utilities
from circumventing the mandatory
purchase requirement under PURPA by
refusing to enter into contracts.1043 The
Commission thus has found that
requiring a QF to have a utility-executed
contract or interconnection agreement,
or requiring the completion of a utilitycontrolled study places too much
control over the LEO in the hands of the
utility and defeats the purpose of a LEO
and is inconsistent with PURPA.1044
When reviewing factors to demonstrate
commercial viability and financial
commitment, states thus should place
emphasis on those factors that show that
the QF has taken meaningful steps to
1042 NorthWestern Comments at 15–16, Portland
General Comments at 20, South Dakota Commission
Comments at 2.
1043 JD Wind 1, LLC, 129 FERC ¶ 61,148 at P 25,
reh’g denied, 130 FERC ¶ 61,127 (citing Order No.
69 FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 30,128 at 30,880; see also
Midwest Renewable Energy Projects, LLC, 116 FERC
¶ 61,017 (2006).
1044 FLS, 157 FERC ¶ 61,211 at P 23 (finding such
requirements ‘‘allows a utility to control whether
and when a legally enforceable obligation exists—
e.g. by delaying the facilities study.’’).
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
develop the QF that are within the QF’s
control to complete, and not on those
factors that a utility controls. For
example, requiring a QF to make a
deposit as Portland General and sPower
proposed or whether the QF has applied
for system impact, interconnection or
other needed studies are the types of
factors that may show that the QF has
taken meaningful steps to develop the
QF that are within the QF’s control and
the type of objective and reasonable
standards that states can consider in
their implementation.1045
696. Requests by parties to expand
utilities’ rights to curtail QF sales are
outside the scope of this proceeding.
Additionally, requests to allow a utility
to reject purchases from QFs if a utility
has no need for additional capacity are
outside the scope of this proceeding.
V. Information Collection Statement
697. The Paperwork Reduction
Act 1046 requires each federal agency to
seek and obtain the Office of
Management and Budget’s (OMB)
approval before undertaking a collection
of information (including reporting,
record keeping, and public disclosure
requirements) directed to 10 or more
persons or contained in a rule of general
applicability. OMB regulations require
approval of certain information
collection requirements contemplated
by proposed rules (including deletion,
revision, or implementation of new
requirements).1047 Upon approval of a
collection of information, OMB will
assign an OMB control number and an
expiration date. Respondents subject to
the filing requirements of a rule will not
be penalized for failing to respond to the
collection of information unless the
collection of information displays a
valid OMB control number.
Public Reporting Burden: The
Commission is revising its regulations
implementing PURPA. At the Notice of
Proposed Rulemaking (NOPR) stage, the
Commission stated the principal
changes that affect information
collection involved the FERC Form No.
556.1048 In response to comments
arguing that the NOPR proposals would
cause additional reporting burdens, in
this final rule we have analyzed
whether there are additional
incremental reporting burdens that
result from other aspects of this final
rule. As described further below, we
find that there is one additional
potential reporting burden arising from
1045 Portland General Comments at 15–16; sPower
Comments at 14–15.
1046 44 U.S.C. 3501–21.
1047 See 5 CFR 1320.11.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
54723
this final rule. It relates to reducing the
PURPA section 210(m) rebuttable
presumption regarding small power
production QFs’ nondiscriminatory
access to certain markets from 20 MW
to 5 MW. Specifically, this reporting
burden would arise from electric
utilities located in markets who choose
to submit to the Commission a PURPA
section 210(m) petition for termination
of the PURPA mandatory purchase
obligation (affecting information
collection FERC–912) for small power
production QFs between 20 MW and 5
MW.
698. With respect to the FERC Form
No. 556, the Commission affirms that
the relevant burdens derive from the
change from the Commission’s current
‘‘one-mile rule’’ for determining
whether generation facilities should be
considered to be at the same site for
purposes of determining qualification as
a qualifying small power production
facility, to allowing an interested person
or other entity challenging a QF
certification the opportunity to file a
protest, without a fee, to rebut the
presumption that affiliated small power
production QFs using the same energy
resource and located more than one
mile and less than 10 miles from the
applicant facility are considered to be at
separate sites.
Specifically, as more fully explained
in section IV.F above, and as
demonstrated by the revised Form No.
556 attached to this final rule (but not
published in the Federal Register or
Code of Federal Regulations),1049 the
Commission makes the following
changes to the FERC Form No. 556
which affect the burden of the
information collection:
• Allow an interested person or other
entity challenging a QF certification the
opportunity to file a protest, without a
fee, to an initial certification (both selfcertification and application for
Commission certification) filed on or
after the effective date of this final rule,
or to a recertification (self-recertification
or application for Commission
recertification) that makes substantive
changes to the existing certification that
is filed on or after the effective date of
this final rule.
• Require all applicants to report the
applicant facility’s geographic
coordinates, rather than only for
applications where there is no street
address.
• Change the current requirement to
identify any affiliated facilities with
electrical generating equipment within
one mile of the applicant facility’s
electrical generating equipment to
instead require applicants to list only
affiliated small power production QFs
using the same energy resource one mile
or less from the applicant facility.
• Additionally require applicants to
list affiliated small power production
QFs using the same energy resource
whose nearest electrical generating
equipment is greater than one mile and
less than 10 miles from the electrical
generating equipment of the applicant
facility.
• Require the applicant to list the
geographic coordinates of the nearest
‘‘electrical generating equipment’’ of
both its own facility and the affiliated
small power production QF in question
based on the definitions adopted in this
final rule.
• Provide space for the applicant to
explain, if it chooses to do so, why the
affiliated small power production QFs
using the same energy resource, that are
more than one mile and less than 10
miles from the electrical generating
equipment of the applicant facility,
should be considered to be at separate
sites from the applicant’s facility,
considering the relevant physical and
ownership factors identified in this final
rule.
As explained in the body of this final
rule, these changes in burden are
appropriate because they are necessary
to meet the statutory requirements
contained in PURPA.
699. In this final rule, the Commission
is revising its regulations implementing
PURPA, which will affect the
information collections for the FERC
Form No. 556 and FERC–912. Below,
the first table includes estimated
changes to the burden and cost of the
FERC Form No. 556 due to the final
rule. As demonstrated by the table, we
believe that QFs will spend more time
to identify any affiliated small power
production QFs that are less than one
mile, between one and 10 miles, and
more than 10 miles, apart. The
Commission expects that there will be
an increase due to the revisions to the
Commission’s regulations, and that the
changes to the ‘‘one-mile rule’’ and the
ability to protest without a fee will
affect self-certifications and applications
for Commission certification.
1048 The change to the FERC–556 described by the
NOPR was submitted under a temporary interim
information collection no., FERC–556A (OMB
Control No. 1902–0316) because another item for
FERC–556 was pending OMB review at the time
and only one item per OMB Control No. can be
pending OMB review at a time. The final rule is
being submitted to OMB under FERC–556.
1049 The Form 556 and instructions will be
available in the Commission’s eLibrary.
PO 00000
Frm 00087
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
54724
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
FERC–556, CHANGES DUE TO FINAL RULE IN DOCKET NOS. RM19–15–000 AND AD16–16–000 1050
Facility type
Filing type
Cogeneration and
Small Power Production Facility ≤
1 MW 1051.
Cogeneration Facility > 1 MW.
Cogeneration Facility > 1 MW.
Small Power Production Facility >
1 MW, ≤ 1 Mile
from Affiliated
Small Power Production QF.
Small Power Production Facility >
1 MW, ≤ 1 Mile
from Affiliated
Small Power Production QF.
Small Power Production Facility >
1 MW, > 1 Mile,
< 10 Miles from
Affiliated Small
Power Production QF.
Small Power Production Facility >
1 MW, > 1 Mile,
< 10 Miles from
Affiliated Small
Power Production QF.
Small Power Production Facility >
1 MW, ≥ 10 Miles
from Affiliated
Small Power Production QF.
Small Power Production Facility >
1 MW, ≥ 10 Miles
from Affiliated
Small Power Production QF.
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
FERC–556,
Total Additional Burden and
Cost Due to
Final Rule.
Number of
respondents
Annual number
of responses
per respondent
Total number
of responses
Increased average
burden hours and
cost per response
($)
Increased total
annual burden
hours and total
annual cost
($)
Increased
annual cost per
respondent
($)
(1)
(2)
(1) * (2) = (3)
(4)
(3) * (4) = (5)
(5) ÷ (1 = (6)
Self-certification ...
no change (692) ..
no change (1.25)
no change (865) ..
no change (1.5
hrs.); $0.
no change
(1,297.5 hrs.);
$0.
0
Self-certification ...
no change (63) ....
no change (1.25)
no change (78.75)
no change (1.5
hrs.); $0.
0
Application for
FERC certification.
Self-certification ...
no change (1) ......
no change (1.25)
no change (1.25)
no change (50
hrs.); $0.
no change
(118.125 hrs.);
$0.
no change (62.5
hrs.); $0.
no change
(899) 1052.
no change (1.25)
no change
(1,123.75).
2 hrs.; $166 .........
2,247.5 hrs.;
186,542.5.
207.5
Application for
FERC certification.
no change (0) ......
no change (1.25)
no change (0) ......
6 hrs.; $498 .........
no change (0
hrs.); $0.
0
Self-certification ...
no change (900) ..
no change (1.25)
no change (1,125)
8 hrs.; $664 .........
9,000 hrs.;
$747,000.
Application for
FERC certification.
no change (0) ......
no change (1.25)
no change (0) ......
12 hrs.; $996 .......
no change (0
hrs.); $0.
Self-certification ...
no change (899) ..
no change (1.25)
no change
(1,123.75).
2 hrs.; $166 .........
2,247.5 hrs.;
$186,542.5.
Application for
FERC certification.
no change (0) ......
no change (1.25)
no change (0) ......
6 hrs.; $498 .........
no change (0
hrs.); $0.
..............................
no change (3,454)
..............................
no change
(4,317.5).
..............................
13,495 hrs.;
$1,120,085.
700. The table below reflects the
additional estimated public reporting
burdens associated with reducing the
PURPA section 210(m) rebuttable
presumption regarding small power
production QFs’ nondiscriminatory
access to certain markets from 20 MW
to 5 MW, which affects the FERC–
912.1053 The FERC–912 is optional, but
1050 The figures in this table reflect estimated
changes to the current OMB-approved inventory for
the FERC Form No. 556 (approved by the Office of
Management and Budget (OMB) on November 18,
2019).
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
Where ‘‘no change’’ is indicated, the current
figure is included parenthetically for information
only. Those parenthetical figures are not included
in the final total for column 5.
Commission staff believes that the industry is
similarly situated in terms of wages and benefits.
Therefore, cost estimates are based on FERC’s 2020
average hourly wage (and benefits) of $83.00/hour.
(The submittal to and approval of OMB in 2019 for
FERC Form No. 556 was based on FERC’s 2018
average annual wage hourly rate of $79.00/hour.
Because the change from the $79.00 hourly rate to
the current $83.00 hourly rate was not due to the
final rule, this chart does not depict this increase.)
1051 Not required to file.
1052 In the FERC Form No. 556 approved by OMB
in 2019, for the category ‘‘Small Power Production
PO 00000
Frm 00088
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
0
830
0
207.5
0
..........................
if electric utilities located in relevant
markets choose to submit to the
Facility > 1 MW, Self-certification,’’ we estimated
the number of respondents at 2,698. We have now
divided that category into three categories: ‘‘Small
Power Production Facility > 1 MW, ≤ 1 Mile from
Affiliated Small Power Production QF,’’ ‘‘Small
Power Production Facility > 1 MW, > 1 Mile, < 10
Miles from Affiliated Small Power Production QF,’’
‘‘Small Power Production Facility > 1 MW, ≥ 10
Miles from Affiliated Small Power Production QF.’’
In this column, the numbers 899, 900, and 899 are
a distribution of those same estimated 2,698
respondents across the three categories.
1053 This information was not included in the
burden estimates in the NOPR.
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
Commission a PURPA section 210(m)
petition for termination of the PURPA
mandatory purchase obligation for small
power production QFs between 20 MW
and 5 MW, then we would expect the
54725
following burdens and cost estimates to
apply.
FERC–912, CHANGES DUE TO FINAL RULE IN DOCKET NOS. RM19–15–000 AND AD16–16–000
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
(Termination of obligation to purchase)
Number of
respondents
Annual number
of responses
per respondent
Total number
of responses
Increased average
hours and cost
per response
($)
Increased total
annual burden hours
and total annual cost
($)
Increased
annual
cost per
respondent
(at $83/hr.)
(1)
(2)
(1) × (2) = (3)
(4)
(3) * (4) = (5)
(5)/(1) = (6)
Electric utility burden of reducing 210(m) rebuttable presumption from 20 MW to 5
MW 1054.
30
1
30
12 hrs.; $996 .............
360 hrs.; $29,880 ......
$996
Total .........................................................
30
1
30
12 hrs.; $996 .............
360 hrs.; $29,880 ......
996
Title: FERC–556 (Certification of
Qualifying Facility (QF) Status for a
Small Power Production or
Cogeneration Facility), and FERC–912
(PURPA Section 210(m) Notification
Requirements Applicable to
Cogeneration and Small Power
Production Facilities).
Action: Revisions to existing
information collections FERC–556 and
FERC–912.
OMB Control No.: 1902–0075 (FERC–
556) and 1902–0237 (FERC–912).
Respondents: Facilities that are selfcertifying their status as a cogenerator or
small power producer or that are
submitting an application for
Commission certification of their status
as a cogenerator or small power
producer; electric utilities filing to
terminate their obligation to purchase,
at avoided cost rates, the output of small
power production QFs between 5 MW
and 20 MW.
Frequency of Information: Ongoing.
Necessity of Information: The
Commission directs the changes in this
final rule revising its implementation of
PURPA in order to continue to meet
PURPA’s statutory requirements.
Internal Review: The Commission has
reviewed the changes and has
determined that such changes are
necessary. These requirements conform
to the Commission’s need for efficient
information collection, communication,
and management within the energy
industry.
701. Interested persons may obtain
information on the reporting
requirements by contacting the Federal
Energy Regulatory Commission, 888
First Street NE, Washington, DC 20426
[Attention: Ellen Brown, Office of the
Executive Director], by email to
DataClearance@ferc.gov or by phone
(202) 502–8663].
1054 The staff estimates a total of 90 discretionary
responses may be submitted in Years 1–3, with an
annual average of 30.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
Please send comments concerning the
collection of information and the
associated burden estimates to: Office of
Information and Regulatory Affairs,
Office of Management and Budget
[Attention: Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission Desk Officer]. Due to
security concerns, comments should be
sent directly to www.reginfo.gov/public/
do/PRAMain. Comments submitted to
OMB should be sent within 30 days of
publication of this notice in the Federal
Register and should refer to FERC–556
(OMB Control No. 1902–0075) and
FERC–912 (OMB Control No. 1902–
0237).
VI. Environmental Analysis
702. The Commission in the NOPR
explained that it was not possible to
determine the environmental effects of
the changes proposed, given the
numerous uncertainties regarding the
potential effects of the changes
proposed. The Commission in the NOPR
stated that, given these uncertainties,
the National Environmental Policy Act
of 1969 (NEPA) 1055 does not require
that the Commission conduct an
environmental review of the proposed
revised PURPA Regulations.1056
A. Comments
703. Several commenters argue that
the Commission erred in failing to
conduct such a review.1057
704. Biological Diversity asserts an
urgent need to take measures to reduce
greenhouse gas emissions to address
climate change.1058 Biological Diversity
states that the Commission’s rationale
for revising the PURPA Regulations,
namely the increased availability of
‘‘fossil gas,’’ requires the Commission to
1055 42
U.S.C. 4321 et seq.
169 FERC ¶ 61,184 at PP 154–55.
1057 Allco Comments at 21–22; Biological
Diversity Comments at 14; NIPPC, CREA, REC, and
OSEIA Comments at 83; Public Interest
Organizations Comments at 21.
1058 Biological Diversity Comments at 2–7.
1056 NOPR,
PO 00000
Frm 00089
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
consider the reasonably foreseeable
impacts on climate and the
environment, including on threatened
and endangered species, in order to
fulfill its responsibilities under NEPA
and the Endangered Species Act
(ESA).1059 Biological Diversity includes
a list of what it alleges are reasonably
foreseeable impacts from increased use
of ‘‘fossil gas.’’ 1060 Biological Diversity
maintains that the proposed revised
PURPA Regulations would prevent
renewable energy development and lock
in ‘‘fossil gas’’ development and supply,
thereby requiring the Commission to
prepare an environmental impact
statement and to obtain a biological
opinion before proceeding to a final
rule.1061
705. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA
state that ‘‘the Commission must, at a
minimum, complete the requisite
scoping and other process associated
with an EA and then revise and reissue,
or abandon, the NOPR after considering
the issues developed in the EA.’’ 1062
NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA argue
that it would not be too speculative for
the Commission to undertake a NEPA
analysis.1063 NIPPC, CREA, REC, and
OSEIA state that it is possible to study
the environmental effects of the NOPR
proposals because the Commission
undertook a NEPA analysis when it first
implemented PURPA, imposing a
moratorium on certifying cogeneration
facilities as QFs until it completed an
1059 Id.
at 14.
at 15–17.
1061 Id. at 17.
1062 NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at
83–85 (citing, e.g., 42 U.S.C. 4332(A); 18 CFR 380.5,
380.4, 380.11; 40 CFR 1500.1, 1502.5; LaFlamme v.
FERC, 852 F.2d 389, 397 (9th Cir. 1988); Am. Bird
Conservancy, Inc. v. FCC, 516 F.3d 1027, 1033–34
(D.C. Cir. 2008); N. Plains Res. Council, Inc. v.
Surface Transp. Bd., 668 F.3d 1067, 1075 (9th Cir.
2011) (N. Plains Res. Council)).
1063 NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at
92–94 (citing, e.g., Am. Bird Conservancy, Inc. v.
FCC, 516 F.3d 1033); N. Plains Res. Council, 668
F.3d at 1076, 1078–79.
1060 Id.
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
54726
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
Environmental Impact Statement (EIS)
and recognizing the environmental
benefits from encouraging the
development of QFs, and also studied
the environmental impacts for Order
No. 888.1064
706. Public Interest Organizations
state that the Commission must prepare
an Environmental Assessment (EA) in
order to support its position that this
rulemaking may not have any
significant foreseeable environmental
impacts.1065 Public Interest
Organizations describe the NOPR’s
‘‘cursory treatment of the Commission’s
environmental review obligations’’ as
undermining NEPA’s purposes ‘‘that
agencies give due consideration to
environmental impacts when making
major environmental decisions, and
guaranteeing that the public is informed
of such impacts.’’ 1066 Public Interest
Organizations argue that states’ exercise
of new flexibility granted by the
proposed revised PURPA Regulations
are reasonably foreseeable indirect and
cumulative impacts that the
Commission must study. Public Interest
Organizations assert that the
Commission likely will ‘‘need to
prepare a full EIS to evaluate the serious
environmental impacts that will result
from dismantling regulations that
continue to play an important role in
development of renewable generation
resources across the country.’’ 1067
707. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA
argue that the Commission has failed to
explain how eliminating the market for
at least 10% to 20% of renewable energy
facilities would have no impact on the
human environment.1068 NIPPC, CREA,
REC, and OSEIA contend that the
Commission has failed to analyze how
the proposals would impact regions like
the Northwest that lack robust
implementation of PURPA, the 21 states
without renewable power standards
(such as the Idaho, whose Legislature
affirmatively refused to adopt a
renewable power standard), or the one
third of the country that is not located
in an RTO or ISO.1069
708. Allco argues that it is reasonably
foreseeable that the proposed revisions
to the PURPA Regulations and resulting
increased fossil fuels use could add
significant levels of greenhouse gas
emissions to the atmosphere and
endanger the climate.1070 The effects of
such endangerment to the climate from
fossil fuel use and reduced renewable
energy QF generation, according to
Allco, include mass extinction of
species, in violation of the ESA.1071
Allco contends that the Commission’s
failure to consult with the U.S. Fish and
Wildlife Service and the National
Marine Fisheries Service (collectively,
the Services) prior to issuing the NOPR
constituted a violation of its obligations
under the ESA, ‘‘to insure that its
actions are not likely to jeopardize the
continued existence of endangered or
threatened species, or result in the
destruction or adverse modification of
critical habitat.’’ 1072
709. According to Allco, the PURPA
NOPR triggered the ESA’s consultation
requirement because the proposed
changes will increase fossil fuel
generation that will, in turn, displace
‘‘over 2 [terawatts (TWs)] of solar
generation over the next 20 years as
compared to the baseline scenario of
application and faithful adherence to
existing PURPA rules.’’ 1073 Allco
alleges that increased fossil-fuel
generation will ‘‘increase land and
ocean temperatures above what they
would have been, . . . resulting in
increased pollution to the waters of the
United States, and harming federally
endangered and threatened species,
including, without limitation, the
Piping plover and the Right whale.’’ 1074
B. Commission Determination
710. We find that no EA or EIS of the
final rule is required. NEPA requires
federal agencies to prepare a detailed
statement on the environmental impact
of ‘‘major Federal actions significantly
affecting the quality of the human
environment.’’ 1075 The Council on
Environmental Quality’s (CEQ)
regulations implementing NEPA
provide that federal agencies can
comply with NEPA by preparing: (a) An
Environmental Impact Statement (EIS);
or (b) an Environmental Assessment
(EA) to determine whether the proposed
action significantly affects the quality of
the human environment and requires
the preparation of an EIS.1076 CEQ
regulations also state that federal
agencies are not obligated to prepare
either an EIS or an EA if they find that
1071 Id.
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
1064 Id.
at 94–96.
1065 Public Interest Organizations Comments at
21.
1066 Id.
1067 Id. at 26.
1068 NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at
86–87.
1069 Id. at 87–88.
1070 Allco Comments at 31.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
1072 Id. at 34 (quoting 16 U.S.C. 1536(a)(2))
(internal quotations omitted).
1073 Id.
1074 Id. at 34–35.
1075 42 U.S.C. 4332(C) (2018); see also Regulations
Implementing the National Environmental Policy
Act, Order No. 486, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 30,783
(1987) (cross-referenced at 41 FERC ¶ 61,284).
1076 40 CFR 1501.4 (2019).
PO 00000
Frm 00090
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
a categorical exclusion applies.1077
Additionally, courts have held that an
EIS or EA is not required under NEPA
‘‘unless there is a particular project that
‘define[s] fairly precisely the scope and
limits of the proposed
development.’ ’’ 1078
711. No EA or EIS of the final rule is
required because, as discussed below,
the final rule does not propose or
authorize, much less define, the scope
and limits of any potential energy
infrastructure and, as a result, there is
no way to determine whether issuance
of the rule will significantly affect the
quality of the human environment. In
the alternative, a categorical exclusion
applies so that an EA or EIS need not
be prepared. For similar reasons, there
is no requirement that the Commission
engage in consultation pursuant to the
ESA with respect to this action.
1. No EIS or EA Is Required
a. There Is No Project That Defines the
Scope and Limits of QF Development
712. In Center for Biological Diversity,
the court held that no NEPA review was
required with respect to actions taken
by the United States Forest Service that
were similar in all relevant respects to
the action taken here by the
Commission in promulgating the final
rule. That case involved the designation
by the Forest Service, pursuant to the
Healthy Forests Restoration Act (HFRA),
of certain forests as ‘‘landscape-scale
areas.’’ Such designation meant that
specific treatments could be proposed to
address insect infestation in those
designated ‘‘landscape-scale areas.’’ 1079
The court held that no NEPA review
was required for the designations,
noting that no specific projects were
proposed for any of the landscape-scale
areas and stating that ‘‘[i]n such
circumstances, ‘any attempt to produce
an [EIS] would be little more than a
study . . . containing estimates of
potential development and attendant
environmental consequences.’ ’’ 1080 The
court concluded that ‘‘unless there is a
particular project that ‘define[s] fairly
1077 CEQ regulations state that a categorical
exclusion ‘‘means a category of actions which do
not individually or cumulatively have a significant
effect on the human environment and which have
been found to have no such effect in procedures
adopted by a federal agency in implementation of
these regulations and for which, therefore, neither
an environmental assessment nor an environmental
impact statement is required.’’ 40 CFR 1508.4
(2019).
1078 Center for Biological Diversity v. Ilano, 928
F.3d 774, 780 (9th Cir. 2019) (Center for Biological
Diversity) (quoting Kleppe v. Sierra Club, 427 U.S.
390, 402 (1976)).
1079 Center for Biological Diversity, 928 F.3d at
778.
1080 Id. at 780 (quoting Kleppe v. Sierra Club, 427
U.S. 390, 402 (1976)).
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
precisely the scope and limits of the
proposed development of the region,’
there can be ‘no factual predicate for the
production of an [EIS] of the type
envisioned by NEPA.’ ’’ 1081
713. Similarly, here, the final rule
does not authorize the development or
construction of any facilities, but simply
addresses the rates that QFs can charge
and certain requirements under which
proposed facilities may qualify as a
QF.1082 The final rule does not fund any
particular QFs, or issue permits for their
construction or operation (neither of
which the Commission has jurisdiction
to do). The Commission does not, in its
regulations or in this final rule,
authorize or prohibit the use of any
particular technology or fuel, nor does
it mandate or prohibit where QFs
should be or are built. This final rule
does not exempt QFs from any Federal,
state, or local environmental, siting, or
similar laws or regulatory requirements,
(again something the Commission has
no authority to do).
714. Even with respect to rates, while
the Commission has established and
here revises the factors and approaches
that states can take into account when
they set QF rates, it is ultimately the
states and not the Commission that set
those rates. The final rule continues to
give states wide discretion and it is
impossible to know what the states may
choose to do in response to this final
rule, whether they will make changes in
their current practices or not, and how
those state choices would impact QF
development and the environment in
any particular state, let along any
particular locale.
715. Moreover, the scope of this final
rule is even less defined than the
landscape-scale area designations at
issue in the Center for Biological
Diversity case. PURPA applies
throughout the entire United States, and
the revisions implemented by the final
rule theoretically could affect future QF
development anywhere in the country.
716. While courts have held that
NEPA requires ‘‘reasonable forecasting,’’
‘‘NEPA does not require a ‘crystal ball’
1081 Id. (quoting Kleppe, 427 U.S. at 402); see also
Northcoast Environmental Center v. Glickman, 136
F.3d 660, 668 (9th Cir. 1998) (citing Kleppe in
support of its holding that NEPA does not require
agency to complete environmental analysis where
environmental effects are speculative or
hypothetical).
1082 See Sugarloaf Citizens Ass’n v. FERC, 959
F.2d 508, 514 n.29 (4th Cir. 1992) (finding that in
the QF certification context ‘‘FERC does little more
than regulate the rates paid by utilities to the
qualifying facility and does not control the
financing, construction or operation of the project.
Although the Facility receives an economic benefit,
no direct federal funding or other substantial
federal assistance is provided, and no licensing
action is involved.’’).
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
inquiry.’’ 1083 Further, an agency ‘‘is not
required to engage in speculative
analysis’’ or ‘‘to do the impractical, if
not enough information is available to
permit meaningful consideration’’ 1084
or to ‘‘foresee the unforeseeable.’’ 1085 In
that vein, ‘‘[i]n determining what effects
are ‘reasonably foreseeable,’ an agency
must engage in ‘reasonable forecasting
and speculation,’ . . . with reasonable
being the operative word.’’ 1086
Environmental impacts are not
reasonably foreseeable if the impacts
would result only through a lengthy
causal chain of highly uncertain or
unknowable events.1087
717. Commenters’ allegations
regarding potentially reduced QF
development hinge on the claim that the
NOPR proposed to ‘‘repeal’’ or
‘‘eliminate’’ critical PURPA Regulations,
which is not true. The Commission
proposed in the NOPR, which this final
rule generally affirms, to clarify some
existing PURPA regulations and modify
other PURPA Regulations to make them
consistent with the statute, based on
changed circumstances since the time
those regulations originally were
promulgated. Any consideration of
whether the revised rules could
potentially result in significant new
environmental impacts due to less QF
development and increased
development of coal, nuclear, and
combined cycle natural gas plants,
would be highly speculative, based on
the difficulty in determining which
additional flexibilities the final rule
provides to the states that each state will
adopt, if any; how such state rules
would impact QF development going
forward; and whether any reduction in
QF renewables would be replaced by
the much greater amount of non-QF
renewable resources with similar
environmental characteristics.1088
718. As was the case in Center for
Biological Diversity, any attempt to
evaluate the environmental effects of the
1083 Vt. Yankee Nuclear Power Corp. v. Nat. Res.
Def. Council, Inc., 435 U.S. 519, 534 (1978) (quoting
Nat. Res. Def. Council, Inc. v. Morton, 458 F.2d 827,
837 (D.C. Cir. 1972)).
1084 N. Plains Res. Council v. Surface Transp.
Board, 668 F.3d 1067, 1078–79 (9th Cir. 2011)
(citation omitted).
1085 Concerned About Trident v. Rumsfeld, 555
F.2d 817, 830 (D.C. Cir. 1976) (citation omitted).
1086 Sierra Club v. U.S. Dep’t of Energy, 867 F.3d
189, 198 (D.C. Cir. 2017) (emphasis in original)
(citation omitted).
1087 See Dep’t of Transp. v. Pub. Citizen, 541 U.S.
752, 767 (2004) (‘‘NEPA requires a ‘reasonably close
causal relationship’ between the environmental
effect and the alleged cause.’’); Metro. Edison Co. v.
People Against Nuclear Energy, 460 U.S. 766, 774
(1983) (noting effects may not fall within section
102 of NEPA because ‘‘the causal chain is too
attenuated’’).
1088 See infra VI.B.2.
PO 00000
Frm 00091
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
54727
final rule by necessity would involve
nothing less than hypothesizing the
potential development of QFs and the
resultant environmental consequences.
Indeed, any attempt by the Commission
to estimate the potential environmental
effects of the final rule would be
considerably more speculative than the
estimates of potential development and
attendant environmental consequences
that the court in Center for Biological
Diversity held are not required under
NEPA. That case involved limited zones
in which some projects to treat insect
infestation almost certainly would be
proposed. Here, it simply is not possible
to provide any reasonable forecast of the
effects of the final rule on future QF
development, whether any affected
potential QF would be a renewable
resource (such as solar or wind) or
employ carbon-emitting technology
(e.g., a fossil-fuel-burning cogenerator or
a waste-coal-burning small power
production facility). Moreover,
environmental effects on land use,
vegetation, water quality, etc. are all
dependent on location, which are
unknown and could be anywhere in the
United States.
719. Because, even more so than in
Center for Biological Diversity, the final
rule does not authorize, or define any
limit on the scope of, any potential QF
or other infrastructure development, any
attempt to prepare an analysis of the
potential effects of the final rule on
future QF development would be so
speculative as to render meaningless
any environmental analysis of these
impacts. Therefore, no such analysis is
required by NEPA.
b. A Categorical Exclusion Applies
720. There is a separate and
independent alternative reason why no
environmental analysis is warranted:
the final rule falls within a categorical
exclusion promulgated by the
Commission pursuant to the CEQ’s
NEPA regulations.1089 Specifically, the
final rule falls within the categorical
exclusion for rules that: (1) Are
clarifying in nature, (2) are corrective in
nature, (3) are procedural in nature, or
(4) do not substantially change the effect
of the regulation being amended.1090
Here, each of the revisions to the
PURPA Regulations implemented by the
1089 CEQ regulations provide that agencies shall
issue procedures that provide specific criteria for
classes of action which ‘‘normally do not require
either an environmental impact statement or an
environmental assessment (categorical exclusion)’’.
40 CFR 1507.3 (2019).
1090 See 18 CFR 380.4(a)(2)(ii) (categorical
exclusion applies to ‘‘promulgation of rules that are
clarifying, corrective, or procedural, or that do not
substantially change the effect of . . . regulations
being amended.’’).
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
54728
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
final rule fits into one of these
categories:
i. Changes That Are Clarifying in Nature
721. Several of the changes to the
PURPA Regulations are clarifying in
nature. These include the changes
clarifying how market prices can be
used to set as-available energy rates,1091
the changes clarifying how fixed energy
rates in contracts or LEOs may be
determined,1092 and the changes
clarifying how competitive solicitations
can be used to set avoided cost rates.1093
Other non-rate related clarifying
revisions in the final rule include a
clarification regarding the relationship
between avoided costs and decreases in
a purchasing utility’s load as a
consequence of retail competition,1094 a
clarification as to how electric
generating equipment should be defined
for purposes of determining whether
small power production facilities are
located at the same site,1095 and a
clarification as to when a LEO is
established.1096
ii. Changes That Are Corrective in
Nature
722. The Commission interprets the
categorical exclusion for changes to its
regulations that are corrective in nature
as including changes needed in order to
ensure that a regulation conforms to the
requirements of the statutory provisions
being implemented by the
regulation.1097 To be clear, the
Commission does not find that its
existing PURPA Regulations were
inconsistent with the statutory
requirements of PURPA when
promulgated. Rather, the Commission
finds that the changes adopted in this
1091 See
Sections IV.B.2–5.
Section IV.B.6.
1093 See Section IV.B.8.
1094 See Section IV.C.
1095 See Section IV.D.2.
1096 See Section IV.H.
1097 For example, the Commission relied on this
categorical exclusion when it revised the PURPA
Regulations in 2006 to comply with the
amendments to PURPA enacted as part of EPAct
2005. See Revised Regulations Governing Small
Power Production and Cogeneration Facilities,
Order No. 671, 114 FERC ¶ 61,102 at P 118. Further,
this interpretation is also consistent with the
Supreme Court’s holding that NEPA review is not
required when an agency’s action is required by
statute. See Dep’t of Transp. v. Pub. Citizen, 541
U.S. 752, 770 (2004) (‘‘where an agency has no
ability to prevent a certain effect due to its limited
statutory authority over the relevant actions, the
agency cannot be considered a legally relevant
‘‘cause’’ of the effect [and] . . . under NEPA and the
implementing CEQ regulations, the agency need not
consider these effects in its EA.’’); see also Safari
Club Intern. v. Jewell, 960 F.Supp.2d 17, 79–80
(D.D.C. 2013) (relying on Dep’t of Transp. v. Pub.
Citizen to hold that NEPA review is not required
for an agency rule issued to comply with a statutory
requirement).
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
1092 See
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
final rule are required to ensure
continued future compliance of the
PURPA Regulations with PURPA, based
on the changed circumstances found by
the Commission in this final rule.
723. Three aspects of the final rule are
corrective in nature. The first is the
change allowing states to require
variable energy rates in QF
contracts.1098 As the Commission
explains above, this change is required
based on the Commission’s finding that,
contrary to the Commission’s
expectation in 1980, there have been
numerous instances where
overestimates and underestimates of
energy avoided costs used in fixed
energy rate contracts have not balanced
out, causing the contract rate to not
violate the statutory avoided cost rate
cap. Giving states the ability to require
energy rates in QF contracts to vary
based on the purchasing utility’s
avoided cost of energy at the time of
delivery ensures that QF rates do not
exceed the avoided cost rate cap
imposed by PURPA.1099
724. The second corrective aspect is
the change in the PURPA Regulations
regarding the determination of what
facilities are located at the same site for
purposes of complying with the
statutory 80 MW limit on small power
production facilities located at the same
site.1100 As explained above, the
Commission found, based on changed
circumstances, that the current one-mile
rule is inadequate to determine which
facilities are located at the same site.
Based on this finding, the Commission
was obligated by PURPA to revise its
definition of when facilities are located
at the same site.1101
725. The third corrective aspect of the
final rule relates to the implementation
of PURPA section 210(m). That statutory
provision allows purchasing utilities to
terminate their obligation to purchase
from QFs that have nondiscriminatory
access to certain statutorily-defined
markets, which the Commission has
determined to be the RTO/ISO markets.
The final rule revises the presumption
in the PURPA Regulations that QFs with
a capacity of 20 MW or less do not have
non-discriminatory access to such
markets, reducing the threshold for such
presumption to 5 MW.1102
726. The Commission has determined
in the final rule that, since the 20 MW
threshold was established in 2005, the
RTO/ISO markets have matured and the
industry has developed a better
1098 See
Section IV.B.7.
1099 Id.
1100 See
Section IV.D.
Section IV.D.1.c.
1102 See Section IV.G.1.
1101 See
PO 00000
Frm 00092
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
understanding of the mechanics of
market participation. This
determination has rendered inaccurate
the presumption currently reflected in
the PURPA Regulations that QFs 20 MW
and below do not have nondiscriminatory access to the relevant
markets. Once the Commission made
this determination, it was appropriate
for the Commission to update the 20
MW threshold to comply with the
requirements of PURPA section
210(m).1103
i. Changes That Are Procedural in
Nature
727. The remaining two revisions
implemented by the final rule are
procedural in nature. The first is a
revision to the procedures that apply to
QF certification.1104 The second is a
revision to the Commission’s Form 556,
used by QFs seeking certification.1105
2. The NEPA Analysis for Promulgation
of the Original PURPA Regulations in
1980 Cannot Be Replicated Here
728. As commenters note, in 1980 the
Commission conducted an EA and later
an EIS for its initial rules implementing
PURPA. Initially, the Commission found
(and the Final EIS also found) that new
diesel cogeneration, and dual-fuel
cogeneration particularly, in New York
City, could cause significant
environmental effects on air quality.1106
In Order No. 70–E, however, the
Commission ultimately opted to treat
such cogeneration the same as all other
cogeneration given, among other things,
that the PURPA Regulations were not
the driving force behind the
development of such cogeneration in
New York City.1107 In doing so, the
Commission emphasized that QF status
was not a license nor a permit to operate
but instead only entitled the QF to a rate
for purchases and to certain exemptions
from regulation. Moreover, QFs were
not exempted from any Federal, state, or
local environmental, siting or other
similar requirements.1108
1103 Id.
1104 See
Section IV.E.
Section IV.F
1106 Final EIS at I–7a.
1107 See Order No. 70–E, 46 FR 33025, 33026
(June 18, 1981).
1108 Id. The Commission stated in its EA that:
The rules provide encouragement to the
development of certain types of facilities. They do
not prevent any facility which does not qualify from
using cogeneration or small power production, or
from using any type of fuel. The rules merely grant
or deny certain benefits to certain facilities.
In this environmental assessment, the
environmental effects of these rules are limited to
the effects resulting from the construction and/or
operation of facilities which occur as a result of the
granting of these benefits, or from changes in the
operating characteristics of existing facilities which
1105 See
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
729. The original PURPA EA for the
pre-existing PURPA Regulations was
based on a market penetration study of
PURPA-induced facilities. In order to
carry out that market penetration study,
the original PURPA EA had to make the
simplifying assumption that the mere
implementation of PURPA would
necessarily result in the development
and operation of certain types of
generation facilities that would not
otherwise be developed.1109 Based on
these types of facilities, that EA
identified specific resource conflicts
related to each type of facility, which
were nothing more than a generalized
listing of potential impacts.1110 That EA
found that, because the various types of
facilities operate differently, there
would be no cumulative impacts and
this finding, coupled with the
geographic distribution of facility
development from the market
penetration study, resulted in a finding
of no significant impact for all types of
facilities except diesel and dual-fueled
cogeneration facilities in the MidAtlantic, which that EA found could
cause significant environmental impacts
on air quality.1111
730. Subsequently, an EIS was
prepared that addressed only air quality
in New York City and the broader MidAtlantic region. The bulk of the EIS
focused on how national, state, and
local air pollution regimes would
address air quality surrounding the
construction and operation of such
facilities.1112
731. Several commenters cite to this
previous NEPA analysis conducted in
connection with the original PURPA
Regulations to support their assertion
that a NEPA analysis similarly should
be possible for this rulemaking.
However, those assertions are
undermined by the fact that
circumstances have changed
significantly since the promulgation of
the original PURPA Regulations in 1980.
Prior to 1980, essentially no QF
generation technologies or other
independent generation facilities (other
results from the granting of these benefits. If a
cogeneration or small power production facility
would be constructed or operated without the
incentives of these rules, the environmental effects
resulting therefrom cannot properly be described as
environmental effects of these rules. However, a
technical and environmental discussion of each
technology is provided whether or not its use is
expected to be encouraged by these rules.
Small Power Production and Cogeneration
Facilities—Environmental Findings; No Significant
Impact and Notice of Intent To Prepare
Environmental Impact Statement, 45 FR 23661,
23664 (Apr. 8, 1980) (Original PURPA EA).
1109 Id. at 23,665.
1110 Id. at 23,675–82.
1111 Id. at 23,679, 23,682–83.
1112 Order No. 70–E, 46 FR at 33026.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
than those used to supply the loads of
the owners rather than to sell at
wholesale) had been constructed. By
contrast, today QF generation
technologies and other independent
generation facilities are common, and
they are predominantly built and
operated outside of PURPA.1113
732. Because there was virtually no
QF or independent power development
in 1980, the original PURPA EA could
reasonably project that the incentives
created by PURPA and the original
PURPA Regulations would lead to
increased development of power
generated by QF technologies. The
market penetration study conducted by
the Commission, and the Commission’s
conclusion that the PURPA Regulations
could lead to an increase in diesel-fired
cogeneration in New York City, were
based on these projections.
733. By contrast, it is not possible
here to make simplifying assumptions
that the mere implementation of the
revised regulations necessarily would
result in specific changes in the
development of particular generation
technologies compared to the status
quo. First, the revisions to the PURPA
regulations are premised on a finding
that, even after the revisions, the
PURPA regulations will continue to
encourage QFs. Consequently, there is
no way to estimate whether any
reduction in QF development, as
opposed to the status quo, will be
focused on one or more of the many
different types of QF technologies, some
of which are renewable resources and
some of which are fueled by fossil
fuels 1114 and have emissions
comparable to non-QF fossil fueled
generators. Moreover, because the rule
primarily increases state flexibility in
setting QF rates, including giving states
the option of not changing their current
rate-setting approaches, there is no way
to develop any estimate of the location
or size of any hypothetical reduction in
QF development.
734. In addition, as mentioned above,
renewable generation technologies
today are commonly, and even
predominantly, built and operated
outside of PURPA. Current projections
show that most new generation
construction will be of renewable
resources.1115 Indeed, the cost of
1113 See
supra P 240.
would include both cogeneration, which
typically is fossil fueled, and those small power
production facilities that are fueled by waste, which
would include a range of fossil fuel-based waste.
See 18 CFR 292.202(b), 292.204(b)(1).
1115 EIA, Annual Energy Outlook 2020, at tbl. 9
(Jan. 29, 2020) (in table see rows labeled
Cumulative Planned Additions and Cumulative
Unplanned Additions in the reference case)
1114 This
PO 00000
Frm 00093
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
54729
renewables has declined so much that
in some regions renewables are the most
cost effective new generation technology
available.1116 Thus, even if the final rule
was to result in reduced renewable QF
development, there is little likelihood
today that hypothetical, unbuilt QFs
necessarily would be replaced by new
conventional fossil fuel generation.
735. Alternatively, in the absence of
these hypothetical, unbuilt QFs, existing
generation units—whose current
emissions, if any, would already be part
of the baseline for any environmental
analysis of the impacts of the final
rule—might continue to operate without
any change in their emissions; in sum,
in the absence of these hypothetical,
unbuilt QFs, emissions would remain at
the baseline and might not increase at
all. Indeed, in the current environment
where stagnant load growth has
prevailed in recent years, this would
seem to be a more likely scenario than
an alternative where these hypothetical,
unbuilt QFs are replaced by brand new
fossil fuel generation that would
increase emissions over the baseline.
736. Given these facts, it would not be
possible to perform a market penetration
study of the effects of the final rule that
would not be wholly speculative.
Without such a study, there could be no
analysis defining the types and
geographic location of facilities that
could serve as the basis for any NEPA
analysis similar to that performed in
1980.
3. This Proceeding Does Not Trigger
Any ESA Consultation Requirement
737. Similar to our finding that it
would be nearly impossible to conduct
a meaningful NEPA review, we disagree
with Biological Diversity and Allco that
either the PURPA NOPR or this final
rule trigger any consultation
requirement under the ESA.
The ESA requires that agencies
consult with the Secretary of the Interior
or the Secretary of Commerce to ‘‘insure
that any action authorized, funded, or
carried out by such agency . . . is not
likely to jeopardize the continued
existence of any endangered species or
threatened species or result in the
destruction or adverse modification of
[critical] habitat of such species.’’ 1117
738. The ESA regulations require
consultation only if the Commission
determines that a proposed action may
affect listed species or critical
habitat.1118 We find that there are no
(Annual Energy Outlook 2020), https://
www.eia.gov/outlooks/aeo/.
1116 See supra P 240.
1117 16 U.S.C. 1536(a)(2).
1118 50 CFR 402.14(a).
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
54730
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
effects from the final rule for which the
Commission could consult with the
Services. Under the ESA regulations, as
recently revised, the effects of an
agency’s action are
all consequences to listed species and critical
habitat that are caused by the proposed
action. A consequence is caused by the
proposed action if it would not occur but for
the proposed action and it is reasonably
certain to occur.1119
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
The ESA regulations also state that a
consequence is not considered to be
caused by a proposed action if ‘‘[t]he
consequence is only reached through a
lengthy causal chain that involves so
many steps as to make the consequence
not reasonably certain to occur.’’ 1120
This determination must be made
‘‘based on clear and substantial
information,’’ 1121 and ‘‘should not be
based on speculation or conjecture.’’ 1122
In addition to the above, the same ESA
regulation states that factors for the
agency to consider when determining
whether a consequence is not caused by
the proposed agency action include: ‘‘(1)
The consequence is so remote in time
from the action under consultation that
it is not reasonably certain to occur; or
(2) [t]he consequence is so
geographically remote from the
immediate area involved in the action
that it is not reasonably certain to
occur[.]’’ 1123
739. Because the NOPR was a
proposed rule that in and of itself had
no legal effect, the NOPR is not an
agency ‘‘action’’ under the regulations
implementing the ESA, which define
agency action as the ‘‘the promulgation
of regulations.’’ 1124 Because the NOPR
did not constitute agency action, the
Commission was not required to engage
in consultation under the ESA prior to
the NOPR’s issuance.
740. In this final rule, we are
promulgating regulations, which does
constitute agency action. Nevertheless,
for the same reasons that an
environmental review of the impacts of
this final rule under NEPA would be
impossible to conduct, there is similarly
no basis to conclude that harm to
endangered species is reasonably certain
to occur as a result of this final rule.
741. We find that the effects on
endangered and threatened species
alleged by Allco are not reasonably
certain to occur, not only because any
1119 50
1120 50
CFR 402.2 (emphasis added).
CFR 402.17(b)(3) (emphasis added).
1121 Id.
1122 Endangered and Threatened Wildlife and
Plants; Regulations for Interagency Cooperation, 84
FR 44976, 44993 (Aug. 27, 2019).
1123 50 CFR 402.17(b).
1124 50 CFR 402.2 (emphasis added).
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
such harm is completely speculative,
but also because it could result only
through a lengthy causal chain of highly
uncertain or unknowable events, none
of which are within the Commission’s
authority to authorize or preclude: (1)
That the final rule causes a reduction in
the aggregate amount of QF capacity
constructed in the future; (2) that any
reduction in renewable resource QFs
would not be offset by increased
construction of renewable resources
outside of PURPA, resulting from either
other incentive programs or simply the
increased cost-competitiveness of such
resources; (3) that construction of such
non-QF renewable resources would
yield an increase in carbon emissions
resulting from the reduction in
renewable resource QFs that is not offset
by other renewable resources; and (4)
that such increase in carbon emissions
would have an adverse effect on
endangered and threatened species.
Furthermore, the consequences of this
rule would be remote in time and
geographically remote because it would
require action by individual generators,
QF or non-QF, to propose, site, permit,
construct, and operate a facility, in
underdetermined locations potentially
anywhere in the United States. In
addition, many of these generators, QF
and non-QF, would be subject to state
approval and permitting requirements
over which the Commission has no
control.
742. Further, there is no support in
the record for Allco’s claim that the
changes proposed in the PURPA NOPR
would displace over 2 TWs of solar
generation over the next 20 years.1125
Allco provides no citation or other
support whatsoever for this assertion
but simply makes the claim with no
elaboration. We find that such
speculation or conjecture provides no
basis upon which to either initiate or
conduct any meaningful consultation
with the Services on the impacts to
endangered species from this final rule.
VII. Regulatory Flexibility Act
Certification
743. The Regulatory Flexibility Act of
1980 (RFA) 1126 generally requires a
description and analysis of rules that
will have significant economic impact
on a substantial number of small
entities. In lieu of preparing a regulatory
flexibility analysis, an agency may
certify that a rule will not have a
significant economic impact on a
substantial number of small entities.1127
The Commission in the NOPR stated
1125 Allco
Comments at 34.
U.S.C. 601–12.
1127 5 U.S.C. 605(b).
1126 5
PO 00000
Frm 00094
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
that the proposed rule would not
significantly impact a substantial
number of small entities. Some
commenters argue otherwise.1128
744. The Small Business
Administration’s (SBA) Office of Size
Standards develops the numerical
definition of a small business.1129 The
SBA size standard for electric utilities is
based on the number of employees,
including affiliates.1130 Under SBA’s
current size standards, the threshold for
a small entity (including its affiliates) is
250 employees for cogeneration and
small power production applicants in
the following NAICS 1131 categories:
• NAICS code 221114 for Solar Electric
Power Generation
• NAICS code 221115 for Wind Electric
Power Generation
• NAICS code 221116 for Geothermal
Electric Power Generation
• NAICS code 221117 for Biomass
Electric Power Generation
• NAICS code 221118 for Other Electric
Power Generation
The threshold for a small entity
(including its affiliates) is 500
employees for NAICS code 221111 for
Hydroelectric Power Generation.
745. This rule directly affects
qualifying small power production
facilities and cogeneration facilities, the
majority of which the Commission
estimates are small businesses. With
respect to the changes related to the
Form No. 556 and new protests allowed
pursuant to this rule, as reflected in the
burden and cost estimates provided
above, the Commission does not
anticipate that any additional reporting
burden or cost imposed on QFs,
regardless of their status as a small or
large business, would be significant.
Those revisions may result in additional
information being submitted by some
small power production QF applicants
(especially those with affiliated small
power production qualifying facilities
using the same energy resource located
over one and less than 10 miles away).
The Commission estimates that less
than 10 percent of QF applications and
self-certifications meet these criteria.
1128 See
Allco Comments at 33.
1129 13
CFR 121.101.
1130 SBA final rule on ‘‘Small Business Size
Standards: Utilities,’’ 78 FR 77343 (Dec. 23, 2013).
1131 The North American Industry Classification
System (NAICS) is an industry classification system
that Federal statistical agencies use to categorize
businesses for the purpose of collecting, analyzing,
and publishing statistical data related to the U.S.
economy. United States Census Bureau, North
American Industry Classification System, https://
www.census.gov/eos/www/naics/ (accessed April
11, 2018).
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
746. In the final analysis, the other
changes in this final rule 1132 largely
impact payments to QFs by electric
utilities. More accurate avoided cost
rates may result in lower payments from
certain electric utilities to certain QFs.
In this regard, the final rule provides
states greater flexibility than they have
today to set the rate that electric utilities
will pay QFs, but there is no way to
know in advance which new flexibility
state regulatory authorities and
nonregulated electric utilities will
exercise, or what impact that new
flexibility might have given the different
circumstances likely to apply to each
determination of avoided cost. Under
the final rule, additionally, states also
have the discretion to continue setting
the rate as they do today and not to
adopt the Commission’ proposed greater
rate flexibilities. Therefore, it is not
possible to estimate what the dollar
impact might be. However, because of
the way PURPA is structured, whatever
the potential dollar impacts of these
changes on small QFs may be, to the
extent that they reduce the amounts
paid to certain QFs, such reductions
could be matched dollar-for-dollar by
savings experienced by purchasing
electric utilities, which should be
flowed through to their retail ratepayers,
some of whom would also tend to
qualify as small entities.1133
747. While Allco argues that the
Commission should have attempted to
minimize the impacts on small
renewable energy producers and
consider alternative structures, the fact
is that these offsetting impacts result
from changes that are necessary to
1132 I.e., use of locational marginal prices,
competitive market price, and use of forecasted
stream of market revenues for energy rate
component of QF contracts or legally enforceable
obligations; use of variable energy rates in QF
contracts or legally enforceable obligations; use of
competitive solicitations to set avoided energy and
capacity rates; reducing the PURPA section 210(m)
rebuttable presumption regarding access to markets
from 20 MW to 5 MW; and the commercial viability
and financial commitment to construct
demonstration necessary to obtaining a legally
enforceable obligation.
1133 While this potential beneficial impact on
retail ratepayers would be an indirect impact of this
final rule, the Small Business Administration Office
of Advocacy encourages such indirect costs to be
analyzed as well: ‘‘Although it is not required by
the RFA, the Office of Advocacy believes that it is
good public policy for the agency to perform a
regulatory flexibility analysis even when the
impacts of its regulation are indirect.’’ SBA, Office
of Advocacy, A Guide for Government Agencies:
How to Comply with the Regulatory Flexibility Act
at 23 (Aug. 2017), https://www.sba.gov/sites/
default/files/advocacy/How-to-Comply-with-theRFA-WEB.pdf. But see Mid-Tex Elec. Co-op., Inc. v.
FERC, 773 F.2d 327, 343 (D.C. Cir. 1985) (‘‘Congress
did not intend to require that every agency consider
every indirect effect that any regulation might have
on small businesses in any stratum of the national
economy.’’).
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
ensure the Commission’s regulations
continue to meet PURPA’s statutory
requirements. For example, allowing
states to use competitive prices may
benefit small QFs inasmuch as the ratesetting process for purchases of energy
from these entities would be more
straightforward and efficient than the
administrative processes currently in
use. Furthermore, providing flexibility
in setting energy rates may result in
state entities approving longer duration
contracts for capacity (at fixed rates) and
energy. The impacts of these changes,
therefore, are reasonable alternatives to
the status quo while adhering to the
requirements of PURPA.
748. This final rule establishes a
rebuttable presumption that a qualifying
small power production facility whose
electrical generating equipment is more
than one but less than 10 miles from
affiliated electrical generating
equipment using the same energy
resource is at a separate site. The
Commission finds that this rebuttable
presumption imposes a lower burden
than imposing a rule that any affiliated
electrical generating equipment less
than 10 miles apart is presumed to be
at the same site. Similarly, the
Commission, while removing the
rebuttable presumption that qualifying
small power production facilities more
than 5 MW but under 20 MW lack
nondiscriminatory access, has provided
factors that such facilities could use to
demonstrate lack of such access—
allowing them to retain the mandatory
purchase obligation. The Commission
estimates that annual additional
compliance costs on industry (detailed
above) will be approximately $1,149,965
(or an average additional burden and
cost per response, of 3.187 hrs. and the
corresponding $264.51) to comply with
these requirements.1134
749. Accordingly, pursuant to section
605(b) of the RFA, the Commission
certifies that this rule will not have a
significant economic impact on a
substantial number of small entities.
VIII. Document Availability
750. In addition to publishing the full
text of this document in the Federal
Register, the Commission provides all
interested persons an opportunity to
view and/or print the contents of this
document via the internet through the
Commission’s Home Page (https://
www.ferc.gov). At this time, the
1134 Annual additional cost of $1,149,965
[($1,120,085 for FERC–556) + (29,880 for FERC–
912)] and average additional burden of 13,855 hours
[(13,495 hrs. for FERC–556) + (360 hrs. for FERC–
912)] divided by the number of affected responses
of 4,347.5 [(4,317.5 for FERC–556) + (30 responses
for FERC–912)].
PO 00000
Frm 00095
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
54731
Commission has suspended access to
the Commission’s Public Reference
Room due to the President’s March 13,
2020 proclamation declaring a National
Emergency concerning the Novel
Coronavirus Disease (COVID–19).
751. From the Commission’s Home
Page on the internet, this information is
available on eLibrary. The full text of
this document is available on eLibrary
in PDF and Microsoft Word format for
viewing, printing, and/or downloading.
To access this document in eLibrary,
type the docket number excluding the
last three digits of this document in the
docket number field.
752. User assistance is available for
eLibrary and the Commission’s website
during normal business hours from the
Commission’s Online Support at 202–
502–6652 (toll free at 1–866–208–3676)
or email at ferconlinesupport@ferc.gov,
or the Public Reference Room at (202)
502–8371, TTY (202)502–8659. Email
the Public Reference Room at
public.referenceroom@ferc.gov.
IX. Effective Dates and Congressional
Notification
753. These regulations are effective
December 31, 2020. The Commission
has determined, with the concurrence of
the Administrator of the Office of
Information and Regulatory Affairs of
OMB, that this rule is not a ‘‘major rule’’
as defined in section 351 of the Small
Business Regulatory Enforcement
Fairness Act of 1996. This final rule is
being submitted to the Senate, House,
Government Accountability Office, and
Small Business Administration.
List of Subjects in 18 CFR Part 292
Electric power plants; Electric
utilities, Reporting and recordkeeping
requirements.
List of Subjects in 18 CFR Part 375
Authority delegations (Government
agencies); Seals and insignia; Sunshine
Act.
By the Commission. Commissioner
Glick is dissenting in part with a
separate statement attached.
Issued: July 16, 2020.
Nathaniel J. Davis, Sr.,
Deputy Secretary.
In consideration of the foregoing, the
Commission amends parts 292 and 375,
chapter I, title 18, Code of Federal
Regulations, as follows.
SUBCHAPTER K—REGULATIONS
UNDER THE PUBLIC UTILITY
REGULATORY POLICIES ACT OF 1978
*
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
*
*
02SER2
*
*
54732
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
PART 292—REGULATIONS UNDER
SECTIONS 201 AND 210 OF THE
PUBLIC UTILITY REGULATORY
POLICIES ACT OF 1978 WITH REGARD
TO SMALL POWER PRODUCTION AND
COGENERATION
1. The authority citation for part 292
continues to read as follows:
■
Authority: 16 U.S.C. 791a–825r, 2601–
2645; 31 U.S.C. 9701; 42 U.S.C. 7101–7352.
2. Amend § 292.101 by adding
paragraphs (b)(12) through (16) to read
as follows:
■
§ 292.101
Definitions.
*
*
*
*
*
(12) Locational marginal price means
the price for energy at a particular
location as determined in a market
defined in § 292.309(e), (f), or (g).
(13) Competitive Price means a Market
Hub Price or a Combined Cycle Price.
(14) Market Hub Price means a price
for as-delivered energy determined
pursuant to § 292.304(b)(7)(i).
(15) Combined Cycle Price means a
price for as-delivered energy determined
pursuant to § 292.304(b)(7)(ii).
(16) Competitive Solicitation Price
means a price for energy and/or capacity
determined pursuant to § 292.304(b)(8).
■ 3. Amend § 292.202 by adding
paragraph (t) to read as follows:
§ 292.202
Definitions.
*
*
*
*
*
(t) Electrical generating equipment
means all boilers, heat recovery steam
generators, prime movers (any
mechanical equipment driving an
electric generator), electrical generators,
photovoltaic solar panels, inverters, fuel
cell equipment and/or other primary
power generation equipment used in the
facility, excluding equipment for
gathering energy to be used in the
facility.
■ 4. Amend § 292.204 by revising
paragraph (a) to read as follows:
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
§ 292.204 Criteria for qualifying small
power production facilities.
(a) Size of the facility—(1) Maximum
size. Except as provided in paragraph
(a)(4) of this section, the power
production capacity of a facility for
which qualification is sought, together
with the power production capacity of
any other small power production
qualifying facilities that use the same
energy resource, are owned by the same
person(s) or its affiliates, and are located
at the same site, may not exceed 80
megawatts.
(2) Method of calculation. (i)(A) For
purposes of this paragraph (a)(2), there
is an irrebuttable presumption that
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
affiliated small power production
qualifying facilities that use the same
energy resource and are located one
mile or less from the facility for which
qualification or recertification is sought
are located at the same site as the
facility for which qualification or
recertification is sought.
(B) For purposes of this paragraph
(a)(2), for facilities for which
qualification or recertification is filed on
or after December 31, 2020 there is an
irrebuttable presumption that affiliated
small power production qualifying
facilities that use the same energy
resource and are located 10 miles or
more from the facility for which
qualification or recertification is sought
are located at separate sites from the
facility for which qualification or
recertification is sought.
(C) For purposes of this paragraph
(a)(2), for facilities for which
qualification or recertification is filed on
or after December 31, 2020, there is a
rebuttable presumption that affiliated
small power production qualifying
facilities that use the same energy
resource and are located more than one
mile and less than 10 miles from the
facility for which qualification or
recertification is sought are located at
separate sites from the facility for which
qualification or recertification is sought.
(D) For hydroelectric facilities,
facilities are considered to be located at
the same site as the facility for which
qualification or recertification is sought
if they are located within one mile of
the facility for which qualification or
recertification is sought and use water
from the same impoundment for power
generation.
(ii) For purposes of making the
determinations in paragraph (a)(2)(i),
the distance between two facilities shall
be measured from the edge of the closest
electrical generating equipment for
which qualification or recertification is
sought to the edge of the nearest
electrical generating equipment of the
other affiliated small power production
qualifying facility using the same energy
resource.
(3) Waiver. The Commission may
modify the application of paragraph
(a)(2) of this section, for good cause.
(4) Exception. Facilities meeting the
criteria in section 3(17)(E) of the Federal
Power Act (16 U.S.C. 796(17)(E)) have
no maximum size, and the power
production capacity of such facilities
shall be excluded from consideration
when determining the size of other
small power production facilities less
than 10 miles from such facilities.
*
*
*
*
*
■ 5. Amend § 292.207 by:
PO 00000
Frm 00096
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
a. Revising paragraphs (a), (b)
intructory text, (b)(2), (c), and (d);
■ b. Adding paragraphs (e) and (f).
The revisions and additions read as
follows:
■
§ 292.207 Procedures for obtaining
qualifying status.
(a) Self-certification. (1) FERC Form
No. 556. The qualifying facility status of
an existing or a proposed facility that
meets the requirements of § 292.203
may be self-certified by the owner or
operator of the facility or its
representative by properly completing a
FERC Form No. 556 and filing that form
with the Commission, pursuant to
§ 131.80 of this chapter, and complying
with paragraph (e) of this section.
(2) Factors. For small power
production facilities pursuant to
§ 292.204, the owner or operator of the
facility or its representative may, when
completing the FERC Form No. 556,
provide information asserting factors
showing that the facility for which
qualification or recertification is sought
is at a separate site from other facilities
using the same energy resource and
owned by the same person(s) or its
affiliates.
(3) Commission action. Selfcertification and self-recertification are
effective upon filing. If no protests to a
self-certification or self-recertification
are timely filed pursuant to paragraph
(c) of this section, no further action by
the Commission is required for a selfcertification or self-recertification to be
effective. If protests to a selfcertification or self-recertification are
timely filed pursuant to paragraph (c) of
this section, a self-certification or selfrecertification will remain effective
until the Commission issues an order
revoking QF certification. The
Commission will act on the protest
within 90 days from the date the protest
is filed; provided that, if the
Commission requests more information
from the protester, the entity seeking
qualification or recertification, or both,
the time for the Commission to act will
be extended to 60 days from the filing
of a complete answer to the information
request. In addition to any extension
resulting from a request for information,
the Commission also may toll the 90day period for one additional 60-day
period if so required to rule on a protest.
Authority to toll the 90-day period for
this purpose is delegated to the
Secretary or the Secretary’s designee.
Absent Commission action before the
expiration of the tolling period, a protest
will be deemed denied, and the selfcertification or self-recertification will
remain effective.
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
(b) Optional procedure—Commission
certification. * * *
(2) General contents of application.
The application must include a properly
completed FERC Form No. 556 pursuant
to § 131.80 of this chapter. For small
power production facilities pursuant to
§ 292.204, the owner or operator of the
facility or its representative may, when
completing the FERC Form No. 556,
provide information asserting factors
showing that the facility for which
qualification is sought is at a separate
site from other facilities using the same
energy resource and owned by the same
person(s) or its affiliates.
*
*
*
*
*
(c) Protests and Interventions. (1)
Filing a Protest. Any person, as defined
in § 385.102(d) of this chapter, who
opposes either a self-certification or selfrecertification making substantive
changes to the existing certification filed
pursuant to paragraph (a) of this section
or an application for Commission
certification or Commission
recertification making substantive
changes to the existing certification filed
pursuant to paragraph (b) of this section
for which qualification or recertification
is filed on or after December 31, 2020,
may file a protest with the Commission.
Any protest to and any intervention in
a self-certification or self-recertification
must be filed in accordance with
§§ 385.211 and 385.214 of this chapter,
on or before 30 days from the date the
self-certification or self-recertification is
filed. Any protestor must concurrently
serve a copy of such filing pursuant to
§ 385.211 of this chapter. Any protest
must be adequately supported, and
provide any supporting documents,
contracts, or affidavits to substantiate
the claims in the protest.
(2) Limitations on protest. Protests
may be filed to any initial selfcertification or application for
Commission certification filed on or
after the effective date of this final rule,
and to any self-recertification or
application for Commission
recertification that are filed on or after
December 31, 2020 that makes
substantive changes to the existing
certification. Once the Commission has
certified an applicant’s qualifying
facility status either in response to a
protest opposing a self-certification or
self-recertification, or in response to an
application for Commission certification
or Commission recertification, any later
protest to a self-recertification or
application for Commission
recertification making substantive
changes to a qualifying facility’s
certification must demonstrate changed
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
circumstances that call into question the
continued validity of the certification.
(d) Response to protests. Any
response to a protest must be filed on
or before 30 days from the date of filing
of that protest and will be allowed
under § 385.213(a)(2) of this chapter.
(e) Notice requirements. (1) General.
An applicant filing a self-certification,
self-recertification, application for
Commission certification or application
for Commission recertification of the
qualifying status of its facility must
concurrently serve a copy of such filing
on each electric utility with which it
expects to interconnect, transmit or sell
electric energy to, or purchase
supplementary, standby, back-up or
maintenance power from, and the State
regulatory authority of each state where
the facility and each affected electric
utility is located. The Commission will
publish a notice in the Federal Register
for each application for Commission
certification and for each selfcertification of a cogeneration facility
that is subject to the requirements of
§ 292.205(d).
(2) Facilities of 500 kW or more. An
electric utility is not required to
purchase electric energy from a facility
with a net power production capacity of
500 kW or more until 90 days after the
facility notifies the facility that it is a
qualifying facility or 90 days after the
utility meets the notice requirements in
paragraph (c)(1) of this section.
(f) Revocation of qualifying status.
(1)(i) If a qualifying facility fails to
conform with any material facts or
representations presented by the
cogenerator or small power producer in
its submittals to the Commission, the
notice of self-certification or
Commission order certifying the
qualifying status of the facility may no
longer be relied upon. At that point, if
the facility continues to conform to the
Commission’s qualifying criteria under
this part, the cogenerator or small power
producer may file either a notice of selfrecertification of qualifying status
pursuant to the requirements of
paragraph (a) of this section, or an
application for Commission
recertification pursuant to the
requirements of paragraph (b) of this
section, as appropriate.
(ii) The Commission may, on its own
motion or on the motion of any person,
revoke the qualifying status of a facility
that has been certified under paragraph
(b) of this section, if the facility fails to
conform to any of the Commission’s
qualifying facility criteria under this
part.
(iii) The Commission may, on its own
motion or on the motion of any person,
revoke the qualifying status of a self-
PO 00000
Frm 00097
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
54733
certified or self-recertified qualifying
facility if it finds that the self-certified
or self-recertified qualifying facility
does not meet the applicable
requirements for qualifying facilities.
(2) Prior to undertaking any
substantial alteration or modification of
a qualifying facility which has been
certified under paragraph (b) of this
section, a small power producer or
cogenerator may apply to the
Commission for a determination that the
proposed alteration or modification will
not result in a revocation of qualifying
status. This application for Commission
recertification of qualifying status
should be submitted in accordance with
paragraph (b) of this section.
■ 6. Amend § 292.304 by:
■ a. Adding paragraph (b)(6) through
(8); and
■ b. Revising paragraphs (d) and (e).
The additions and revisions read as
follows:
§ 292.304
Rates for purchases.
*
*
*
*
*
(b) Relationship to avoided costs.
* * *
(6) Locational Marginal Price. There is
a rebuttable presumption that a state
regulatory authority or nonregulated
electric utility may use a Locational
Marginal Price as a rate for as-available
qualifying facility energy sales to
electric utilities located in a market
defined in § 292.309(e), (f), or (g).
(7) Competitive Price. A state
regulatory authority or nonregulated
electric utility may use a Competitive
Price as a rate for as-available qualifying
facility energy sales to electric utilities
located outside a market defined in
§ 292.309(e), (f), or (g). A Competitive
Price may be either a Market Hub Price
or a Combined Cycle Price, determined
as follows:
(i) A Market Hub Price is a price
established at a liquid market hub
which a state regulatory authority or
nonregulated electric utility determines
represents an appropriate measure of
the electric utility’s avoided cost for asavailable energy, and is a hub to which
the electric utility has reasonable access,
based on an evaluation by the state
regulatory authority or nonregulated
electric utility of the relevant factors,
including but not limited to the
following:
(A) Whether the hub is sufficiently
liquid that prices at the hub represent a
competitive price;
(B) Whether prices developed at the
hub are sufficiently transparent;
(C) Whether the electric utility has the
ability to deliver power from such hub
to its load, even if its load is not directly
connected to the hub; and
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
54734
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
(D) Whether the hub represents an
appropriate market to derive an energy
price for the electric utility’s purchases
from the relevant qualifying facility
given the electric utility’s physical
proximity to the hub or other factors.
(ii) A Combined Cycle Price is a price
determined pursuant to a formula
established by a state regulatory
authority or nonregulated electric utility
using published natural gas price
indices, a proxy heat rate, and variable
operations and maintenance costs for an
efficient natural gas combined-cycle
generating facility. Before establishing
such a formula rate, a state regulatory
authority or nonregulated electric utility
must determine that the resulting
Combined Cycle Price represents an
appropriate measure of the purchasing
electric utility’s avoided cost for energy,
based on its evaluation of the relevant
factors, including but not limited to the
following:
(A) Whether the cost of energy from
an efficient natural gas combined cycle
generating facility represents a
reasonable measure of a competitive
price in the purchasing electric utility’s
region;
(B) Whether natural gas priced
pursuant to particular proposed natural
gas price indices would be available in
the relevant market;
(C) Whether there should be an
adjustment to the natural gas price to
appropriately reflect the cost of
transporting natural gas to the relevant
market; and
(D) Whether the proxy heat rate used
in the formula should be updated
regularly to reflect improvements in
generation technology.
(8) Competitive Solicitation Price. (i)
A state regulatory authority or
nonregulated electric utility may use a
price determined pursuant to a
competitive solicitation process to
establish qualifying facility energy and/
or capacity rates for sales to electric
utilities, provided that such competitive
solicitation process is conducted
pursuant to procedures ensuring the
solicitation is conducted in a
transparent and non-discriminatory
manner including, but not limited to,
the following:
(A) The solicitation process is an open
and transparent process that includes,
but is not limited to, providing equally
to all potential bidders substantial and
meaningful information regarding
transmission constraints, levels of
congestion, and interconnections,
subject to appropriate confidentiality
safeguards;
(B) Solicitations are open to all
sources, to satisfy that electric utility’s
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
capacity needs, taking into account the
required operating characteristics of the
needed capacity;
(C) Solicitations are conducted at
regular intervals;
(D) Solicitations are subject to
oversight by an independent
administrator; and
(E) Solicitations are certified as
fulfilling the above criteria by the
relevant state regulatory authority or
nonregulated electric utility through a
post-solicitation report.
(ii) To the extent that the electric
utility procures all of its capacity,
including capacity resources
constructed or otherwise acquired by
the electric utility, through a
competitive solicitation process
conducted pursuant to paragraph
(b)(8)(i) of this section, the electric
utility shall be presumed to have no
avoided capacity costs unless and until
it determines to acquire capacity outside
of such competitive solicitation process.
However, the electric utility shall
nevertheless be required to purchase
energy from qualifying small power
producers and qualifying cogeneration
facilities.
(iii) To the extent that the electric
utility does not procure all of its
capacity through a competitive
solicitation process conducted pursuant
to paragraph (b)(8)(i) of this section,
then there shall be no presumption that
the electric utility has no avoided
capacity costs.
*
*
*
*
*
(d) Purchases ‘‘as available’’ or
pursuant to a legally enforceable
obligation. (1) Each qualifying facility
shall have the option either:
(i) To provide energy as the qualifying
facility determines such energy to be
available for such purchases, in which
case the rates for such purchases shall
be based on the electric utility’s avoided
cost for energy calculated at the time of
delivery; or
(ii) To provide energy or capacity
pursuant to a legally enforceable
obligation for the delivery of energy or
capacity over a specified term, in which
case the rates for such purchases shall,
except as provided in paragraph (d)(2)
of this section, be based on either:
(A) The avoided costs calculated at
the time of delivery; or
(B) The avoided costs calculated at
the time the obligation is incurred.
(iii) The rate for delivery of energy
calculated at the time the obligation is
incurred may be based on estimates of
the present value of the stream of
revenue flows of future locational
marginal prices, or Competitive Prices
during the anticipated period of
delivery.
PO 00000
Frm 00098
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
(2) Notwithstanding paragraph
(d)(1)(ii)(B) of this section, a state
regulatory authority or nonregulated
electric utility may require that rates for
purchases of energy from a qualifying
facility pursuant to a legally enforceable
obligation vary through the life of the
obligation, and be set at the electric
utility’s avoided cost for energy
calculated at the time of delivery.
(3) Obtaining a legally enforceable
obligation. A qualifying facility must
demonstrate commercial viability and
financial commitment to construct its
facility pursuant to criteria determined
by the state regulatory authority or
nonregulated electric utility as a
prerequisite to a qualifying facility
obtaining a legally enforceable
obligation. Such criteria must be
objective and reasonable.
(e) Factors affecting rates for
purchases. (1) A state regulatory
authority or nonregulated electric utility
may establish rates for purchases of
energy from a qualifying facility based
on a purchasing electric utility’s
locational marginal price calculated by
the applicable market defined in
§ 292.309(e), (f), or (g), or the purchasing
electric utility’s applicable Competitive
Price. Alternatively, a state regulatory
authority or nonregulated electric utility
may establish rates for purchases of
energy and/or capacity from a qualifying
facility based on a Competitive
Solicitation Price. To the extent that
capacity rates are not set pursuant to
this section, capacity rates shall be set
pursuant to subsection (2).
(2) To the extent that a state
regulatory authority or nonregulated
electric utility does not set energy and/
or capacity rates pursuant to paragraph
(e)(1) of this section, the following
factors shall, to the extent practicable,
be taken into account in determining
rates for purchases from a qualifying
facility:
(i) The data provided pursuant to
§ 292.302(b), (c), or (d), including State
review of any such data;
(ii) The availability of capacity or
energy from a qualifying facility during
the system daily and seasonal peak
periods, including:
(A) The ability of the electric utility
to dispatch the qualifying facility;
(B) The expected or demonstrated
reliability of the qualifying facility;
(C) The terms of any contract or other
legally enforceable obligation, including
the duration of the obligation,
termination notice requirement and
sanctions for non-compliance;
(D) The extent to which scheduled
outages of the qualifying facility can be
usefully coordinated with scheduled
outages of the electric utility’s facilities;
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
(E) The usefulness of energy and
capacity supplied from a qualifying
facility during system emergencies,
including its ability to separate its load
from its generation;
(F) The individual and aggregate
value of energy and capacity from
qualifying facilities on the electric
utility’s system; and
(G) The smaller capacity increments
and the shorter lead times available
with additions of capacity from
qualifying facilities; and
(iii) The relationship of the
availability of energy or capacity from
the qualifying facility as derived in
paragraph (e)(2)(ii) of this section, to the
ability of the electric utility to avoid
costs, including the deferral of capacity
additions and the reduction of fossil
fuel use; and
(iv) The costs or savings resulting
from variations in line losses from those
that would have existed in the absence
of purchases from a qualifying facility,
if the purchasing electric utility
generated an equivalent amount of
energy itself or purchased an equivalent
amount of electric energy or capacity.
*
*
*
*
*
■ 7. Amend § 292.309 by revising
paragraphs (c), (d), (e), and (f) to read as
follows:
§ 292.309 Termination of obligation to
purchase from qualifying facilities.
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
*
*
*
*
*
(c) For purposes of paragraphs (a)(1),
(2) and (3) of this section, with the
exception of paragraph (d) of this
section, there is a rebuttable
presumption that a qualifying facility
has nondiscriminatory access to the
market if it is eligible for service under
a Commission-approved open access
transmission tariff or Commission-filed
reciprocity tariff, and Commissionapproved interconnection rules.
(1) If the Commission determines that
a market meets the criteria of paragraphs
(a)(1), (2) or (3) of this section, and if a
qualifying facility in the relevant market
is eligible for service under a
Commission-approved open access
transmission tariff or Commission-filed
reciprocity tariff, a qualifying facility
may seek to rebut the presumption of
access to the market by demonstrating,
inter alia, that it does not have access
to the market because of operational
characteristics or transmission
constraints.
(2) For purposes of paragraphs (a)(1),
(2), and (3) of this section, a qualifying
small power production facility with a
capacity between 5 megawatts and 20
megawatts may additionally seek to
rebut the presumption of access to the
market by demonstrating that it does not
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
have access to the market in light of
consideration of other factors,
including, but not limited to:
(i) Specific barriers to connecting to
the interstate transmission grid, such as
excessively high costs and pancaked
delivery rates;
(ii) Unique circumstances impacting
the time or length of interconnection
studies or queues to process the small
power production facility’s
interconnection request;
(iii) A lack of affiliation with entities
that participate in the markets in
paragraphs (a)(1), (2), and (3) of this
section;
(iv) The qualifying small power
production facility has a predominant
purpose other than selling electricity
and should be treated similarly to
qualifying cogeneration facilities;
(v) The qualifying small power
production facility has certain
operational characteristics that
effectively prevent the qualifying
facility’s participation in a market; or
(vi) The qualifying small power
production facility lacks access to
markets due to transmission constraints.
The qualifying small power production
facility may show that it is located in an
area where persistent transmission
constraints in effect cause the qualifying
facility not to have access to markets
outside a persistently congested area to
sell the qualifying facility output or
capacity.
(d)(1) For purposes of paragraphs
(a)(1), (2), and (3) of this section, there
is a rebuttable presumption that a
qualifying cogeneration facility with a
capacity at or below 20 megawatts does
not have nondiscriminatory access to
the market.
(2) For purposes of paragraphs (a)(1),
(2), and (3) of this section, there is a
rebuttable presumption that a qualifying
small power production facility with a
capacity at or below 5 megawatts does
not have nondiscriminatory access to
the market.
(3) Nothing in paragraphs (d)(1)
through (3) of this section affects the
rights the rights or remedies of any party
under any contract or obligation, in
effect or pending approval before the
appropriate State regulatory authority or
non-regulated electric utility on or
before December 31, 2020, to purchase
electric energy or capacity from or to
sell electric energy or capacity to a small
power production facility between 5
megawatts and 20 megawatts under this
Act (including the right to recover costs
of purchasing electric energy or
capacity).
(4) For purposes of implementing
paragraphs (d)(1) and (2) of this section,
the Commission will not be bound by
PO 00000
Frm 00099
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
54735
the standards set forth in
§ 292.204(a)(2).
(e) Midcontinent Independent System
Operator, Inc. (MISO), PJM
Interconnection, L.L.C. (PJM), ISO New
England Inc. (ISO–NE), and New York
Independent System Operator, Inc.
(NYISO) qualify as markets described in
paragraphs (a)(1)(i) and (ii) of this
section, and there is a rebuttable
presumption that small power
production facilities with a capacity
greater than 5 megawatts and
cogeneration facilities with a capacity
greater than 20 megawatts have
nondiscriminatory access to those
markets through Commission-approved
open access transmission tariffs and
interconnection rules, and that electric
utilities that are members of such
regional transmission organizations or
independent system operators (RTO/
ISOs) should be relieved of the
obligation to purchase electric energy
from the qualifying facilities. A
qualifying facility may seek to rebut this
presumption by demonstrating, inter
alia, that:
(1) The qualifying facility has certain
operational characteristics that
effectively prevent the qualifying
facility’s participation in a market; or
(2) The qualifying facility lacks access
to markets due to transmission
constraints. The qualifying facility may
show that it is located in an area where
persistent transmission constraints in
effect cause the qualifying facility not to
have access to markets outside a
persistently congested area to sell the
qualifying facility output or capacity.
(f) The Electric Reliability Council of
Texas (ERCOT) qualifies as a market
described in paragraph (a)(3) of this
section, and there is a rebuttable
presumption that small power
production facilities with a capacity
greater than five megawatts and
cogeneration facilities with a capacity
greater than 20 megawatts have
nondiscriminatory access to that market
through Public Utility Commission of
Texas (PUCT) approved open access
protocols, and that electric utilities that
operate within ERCOT should be
relieved of the obligation to purchase
electric energy from the qualifying
facilities. A qualifying facility may seek
to rebut this presumption by
demonstrating, inter alia, that:
(1) The qualifying facility has certain
operational characteristics that
effectively prevent the qualifying
facility’s participation in a market; or
(2) The qualifying facility lacks access
to markets due to transmission
constraints. The qualifying facility may
show that it is located in an area where
persistent transmission constraints in
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
54736
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
effect cause the qualifying facility not to
have access to markets outside a
persistently congested area to sell the
qualifying facility output or capacity.
*
*
*
*
*
PART 375—THE COMMISSION
8. The authority citation for part 375
continues to read as follows:
■
Authority: 5 U.S.C. 551–557; 15 U.S.C.
717–717w, 3301–3432; 16 U.S.C. 791–825r,
2601–2645; 42 U.S.C. 7101–7352.
9. Amend § 375.302 by revising
paragraph (v) to read as follows:
■
§ 375.302
Delegations to the Secretary.
*
*
*
*
*
(v) Toll the time for action on requests
for rehearing, and toll the time for
action on protested self-certifications
and self-recertifications of qualifying
facilities.
The following will not appear in the
Code of Federal Regulations.
UNITED STATES OF AMERICA FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION
Docket Nos.
Qualifying Facility Rates and Requirements ...................................................................................................................................
Implementation Issues Under the Public Utility Regulatory Policies Act of 1978 ...........................................................................
(Issued July 16, 2020)
GLICK, Commissioner, dissenting in part:
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
1. I dissent in part from today’s final
rule (Final Rule 1) because it effectively
guts the Commission’s implementation
of the Public Utility Regulatory Policies
Act (PURPA).2 The Commission’s basic
responsibilities under PURPA are threefold: (1) To encourage the development
of qualifying facilities (QFs); (2) to
prevent discrimination against QFs by
incumbent utilities; and (3) to ensure
that the resulting rates paid by
electricity customers remain just and
reasonable, in the public interest, and
do not exceed the incremental costs to
the utility of alternative energy.3 I do
not believe that today’s Final Rule
satisfies those responsibilities. Instead,
the Final Rule raises as many questions
as it answers, not least of which is the
long-term legal viability of an approach
that does so little to encourage QF
development.
2. Although I have concerns about
many of the individual changes
imposed by the Final Rule,4 I remain, on
a broader level, dismayed that the
Commission is attempting to
accomplish via administrative fiat what
Congress has repeatedly declined to do
via legislation. I am especially
disappointed because Congress
expressly provided the Commission
with a different avenue for
1 Qualifying Facility Rates and Requirements
Implementation Issues Under the Public Utility
Regulatory Policies Act of 1978, Order No. 872, 172
FERC ¶ 61,041 (2020) (Final Rule).
2 Public Law 95–617, 92 Stat. 3117 (1978).
3 See 16 U.S.C. 824a–3(a)–(b) (2018).
4 Notwithstanding those concerns, I support
certain aspects of this Final Rule. First and
foremost, I agree with the update to the ‘‘one-mile’’
rule, which prior to today provided an irrebuttable
presumption that resources located more than one
mile apart are separate QFs. In addition, I support
requiring that QFs demonstrate commercial
viability before securing a legally enforceable
obligation with the relevant utility. Finally, I also
support the revision to allow stakeholders to protest
a QF’s self-certification.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
‘‘modernizing’’ our administration of
PURPA. The Energy Policy Act of 2005
gave the Commission the authority to
excuse utilities from their obligations
under PURPA where QFs have nondiscriminatory access to competitive
wholesale markets.5 Had we pursued
reforms based on those provisions,
rather than gutting our longstanding
regulations, I believe we could have
reached a durable, consensus solution
that would ultimately have done more
for all interested parties, even those that
may celebrate the immediate effects of
this Final Rule.
I. PURPA’s Continuing Relevance Is an
Issue for Congress To Decide
3. This proceeding began with a bang.
My colleagues championed the
proposed rule as a ‘‘truly significant’’
action that would fundamentally
overhaul the Commission’s
implementation of PURPA.6 And so it
was. The NOPR proposed to alter almost
every significant aspect of the
Commission’s PURPA regulations,
thereby transforming the foundation on
which the Commission had carried out
its statutory responsibility to
‘‘encourage’’ the development of QFs.
4. I dissented from the NOPR in large
part because I believe that it is not the
Commission’s role to sit in judgment of
a duly enacted statute and determine
whether it has outlived its usefulness.
As I explained, ‘‘almost from the
moment PURPA was passed, Congress
began to hear many of the arguments
being used today to justify scaling the
law back.’’ 7 Congress, however, has
seen fit to significantly amend PURPA
only once in its more-than-forty-year
lifespan. As part of the Energy Policy
5 Public
Law 109–58, 1253, 119 Stat. 594 (2005).
2019 Commission Meeting Tr. at 8.
7 Qualifying Facility Rates and Requirements
Implementation Issues Under the Public Utility
Regulatory Policies Act of 1978, Notice of Proposed
Rulemaking, 168 FERC ¶ 61,184 (2019) (NOPR)
(Glick, Comm’r, dissenting in part at P 3).
6 Sept.
PO 00000
Frm 00100
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
RM19–15–000
AD16–16–000
Act of 2005, Congress amended PURPA,
leaving in place the law’s basic
framework, while adding a series of
provisions that allowed the Commission
to excuse utilities from its requirements
in regions of the country with
sufficiently competitive wholesale
energy markets.8 And while Congress
considered numerous proposals to
further reform the law, it never saw fit
to act on them.9 Against that
background, I could not support my
colleagues’ willingness to ‘‘remove[ ] an
important debate from the halls of
Congress and isolate[] it within the
Commission.’’ 10 Whatever your
position on PURPA—and I recognize
views vary widely—‘‘what should
concern all of us is that resolving these
sorts of questions by regulatory edict
rather than congressional legislation is
neither a durable nor desirable approach
for developing energy policy.’’ 11
5. Today’s Final Rule retreats from
much of the original rationale used to
support the NOPR, but the effect is the
same: The Commission is
administratively gutting PURPA. Make
no mistake, although the Commission
has dropped much of the NOPR
preamble’s opening screed against
PURPA’s continuing relevance, this
Final Rule is a full-throated
endorsement of the conclusion that
PURPA has outlived its usefulness. And
while walking back the argument that
PURPA is antiquated may reduce the
risk that this Final Rule is overturned on
appeal, that does not change the fact
that today’s Final Rule usurps what
should be Congress’s proper role.
6. Throughout this proceeding, the
Commission has been quick to point to
Congress’s directive to from time to time
8 Public
Law 109–58, 1253, 119 Stat. 594 (2005).
Solar Energy Industries Association (SEIA)
Comments at 11.
10 NOPR, 168 FERC ¶ 61,184 (Glick, Comm’r,
dissenting in part at P 4).
11 Id.
9 See
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
amend our regulations implementing
PURPA.12 This Final Rule, however, is
a wholesale overhaul of the
Commission’s PURPA regulations that
reflects a deep skepticism of the need
for the law we are charged with
implementing. I doubt that is what
Congress had in mind when it gave us
responsibility for periodically updating
our implementing regulations.
II. The Commission’s Proposed Reforms
Are Inconsistent With Our Statutory
Mandate
7. PURPA directs the Commission to
adopt such regulations as are ‘‘necessary
to encourage’’ QFs,13 including by
establishing rates for sales by QFs that
are just and reasonable and by ensuring
that such rates ‘‘shall not discriminate’’
against QFs.14 As explained below,
many of the changes adopted by the
Commission in the Final Rule fail to
meet that standard. In addition, many of
the reforms are unsupported—or, in
many cases, contradicted—by the
evidence in the record.15 Accordingly, I
believe today’s Final Rule is not just
poor public policy, but also arbitrary
and capricious agency action.
A. Avoided Cost
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
8. The Final Rule adopts two
fundamental changes to how QF rates
are determined. First, and most
importantly, it eliminates the
requirement that a utility must afford a
QF the option to enter a contract at a
rate for energy that is either fixed for the
duration of the contract or determined
at the outset—e.g., based on a forward
curve reflecting estimated prices over
the term of the contract.16 Second, it
presumptively allows states to set the
rate for as-available energy at the
relevant locational marginal price (LMP)
or a similarly ‘‘competitive market
price.’’ 17 The record in this proceeding
does not support either of those
changes.
12 Final Rule, 172 FERC ¶ 61,041 at PP 24, 48, 54,
67, 296, 628; NOPR, 168 FERC ¶ 61,184 at PP 4, 16,
29, 155.
13 A QF is a cogeneration facility or a small power
production facility. See 18 CFR 292.101(b)(1)
(2019).
14 16 U.S.C. 824a–3(a)–(b).
15 Genuine Parts Co. v. EPA, 890 F.3d 304, 312
(D.C. Cir. 2018) (‘‘[A]n agency cannot ignore
evidence that undercuts its judgment; and it may
not minimize such evidence without adequate
explanation.’’) (citations omitted); id. (‘‘Conclusory
explanations for matters involving a central factual
dispute where there is considerable evidence in
conflict do not suffice to meet the deferential
standards of our review.’’ (quoting Int’l Union,
United Mine Workers v. Mine Safety & Health
Admin., 626 F.3d 84, 94 (D.C. Cir. 2010)).
16 Final Rule, 172 FERC ¶ 61,041 at P 253.
17 Id. PP 151, 189, 211.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
i. Elimination of Fixed Energy Rate
9. Prior to today’s Final Rule, a QF
generally had two options for selling its
output to a utility. Under the first
option, the QF could sell its energy on
an as-available basis and receive an
avoided cost rate calculated at the time
of delivery. This is generally known as
the as-available option. Under the
second option, a QF could enter into a
fixed-duration contract at an avoided
cost rate that was fixed either at the time
the QF established a legally enforceable
obligation (LEO) or at the time of
delivery. This is generally known as the
contract option. The ability to choose
between both types of sale options
played an important role in fostering the
development of a variety of QFs. For
example, the as-available option
provided a way for QFs whose principal
business was not generating electricity,
such as industrial cogeneration
facilities, to monetize their excess
electricity generation. The contract
option, by contrast, provided QFs who
were principally in the business of
generating electricity, such as small
renewable electricity generators, a stable
option that would allow them to secure
financing. Together, the presence of
these two options allowed the
Commission to satisfy its statutory
mandate to encourage the development
of QFs and ensured that the rates they
received were non-discriminatory.
10. The Final Rule eliminates the
requirement that states provide a
contract option that includes a fixed
energy rate.18 Prior to this proceeding,
the Commission recognized time and
again that fixed-price contracts play an
essential role in the financing of QF
facilities, making them a necessary
element of any effort to encourage QF
development, at least in certain regions
of the country.19 In addition, fixed-price
contracts have helped prevent
discrimination against QFs by ensuring
that they are not structurally
disadvantaged relative to vertically
18 Id.
P 253.
e.g., Small Power Production and
Cogeneration Facilities; Regulations Implementing
Section 210 of the Public Utility Regulatory Policies
Act of 1978, Order No. 69, FERC Stats. & Regs.
¶ 30,128, at 30,880, order on reh’g sub nom. Order
No. 69–A, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 30,160 (1980), aff’d
in part vacated in part, Am. Elec. Power Serv. Corp.
v. FERC, 675 F.2d 1226 (D.C. Cir. 1982), rev’d in
part sub nom. Am. Paper Inst. v. Am. Elec. Power
Serv. Corp., 461 U.S. 402 (1983). (justifying the rule
on the basis of ‘‘the need for certainty with regard
to return on investment in new technologies’’);
NOPR, 168 FERC ¶ 61,184 at P 63 (‘‘The
Commission’s justification for allowing QFs to fix
their rate at the time of the LEO for the entire term
of a contract was that fixing the rate provides
certainty necessary for the QF to obtain
financing.’’); Windham Solar LLC, 157 FERC
¶ 61,134, at P 8 (2016).
19 See,
PO 00000
Frm 00101
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
54737
integrated utilities that are guaranteed to
recover the costs of their prudently
incurred investments through retail
rates.20
11. If anything, the record before us
confirms the continuing importance of
fixed-price contracts. Numerous entities
with experience financing and
developing QFs explain that a fixed
revenue stream of some sort is necessary
to obtain the financing needed to
develop a new QF.21 The fixed revenue
stream is particularly important because
QFs are overwhelmingly developed
outside of the organized markets,
meaning that developers cannot
necessarily obtain hedging contracts to
create the revenue predictability needed
to obtain financing.22 And that is why
the Final Rule’s parade of statistics
about the growth of renewables misses
the point.23 It is true that, primarily in
20 See, e.g., ELCON Comments at 21–22 (‘‘More
varible avoided cost rates will result in unintended
consequences that result in less competitive
conditions and may leave consumers worse off, as
utility self-builds do not face the same market risk
exposure. Pushing more market risk to QFs while
utility assets remain insulated from markets creates
an investment risk asymmetry. This puts QFs at a
competitive disadvantage’’); South Carolina Solar
Business Association Comments at 8 (‘‘[A]savailable rates for QFs in vertically-integrated states
therefore discriminate against QFs by requiring QFs
to enter into contracts at substantially and
unjustifiably different terms than incumbent
utilities.’’); Southern Environmental Law Center
Supplement Comments, Docket No. AD16–16–000,
at 6–8 (Oct. 17, 2018) (explaining that vertically
integrated utilities in Indiana, Alabama, Virginia
and Tennessee only offer short-term rates to QFs);
sPower Comments at 13; see also Statement of
Travis Kavulla, Docket No. AD16–16–000, at 2 (June
29, 2016).
21 See, e.g., SEIA Comments at 29; North Carolina
Attorney General’s Office Comments at 5; Con Ed
Development Comments at 3; South Carolina Solar
Business Association Comments at 6; sPower
Comments at 11; Resources for the Future
Comments at 6–7.
22 See, e.g., SEIA Comments at 29–30 (‘‘As both
Mr. Shem and Mr. McConnell explain, financial
hedge products are not available outside of ISO/
RTO markets.’’); Resources for the Future
Comments at 6–7 (‘‘[W]hile hedge products do
support wind and solar project financing, they
would not be suited for most QF projects. To hedge
energy prices, wind projects have used three
products: bank hedges, synthetic power purchase
agreements (synthetic PPAs), and proxy revenue
swaps . . . . From U.S. project data for 2017 and
2018, the smallest wind project securing such a
hedge was 78 MW, and most projects were well
over 100 MW. Additionally, as hedges rely on
wholesale market access and liquid electricity
trading, all of the projects were in ISO regions.’’)
(emphasis added).
23 Harvard Electricity Law Comments at 22
(referring to a similar statistical parade in the NOPR
and observing that ‘‘[a]ll [the Commission] can
actually conclude from this loosely connected array
of facts, data, and speculation is that some non-QF
generators are developed with variable-rate energy
contracts. That unremarkable conclusion has no
bearing on whether repeal will discourage QF
development by ‘materially affect[ing] the ability of
QFs to obtain financing.’ ’’ (citing NOPR, 168 FERC
¶ 61,184 at P 69)); SEIA Comments at 30.
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
54738
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
organized markets, independently
developed renewables are able to
develop without the entitlement to a
fixed-price contract for energy from the
relevant utility.24 But the growth of
renewables and their financeability in
organized markets tells us almost
nothing about what is required to
sufficiently encourage QFs outside those
markets.25
12. It would be one thing to eliminate
the requirement to provide a fixed-price
option for energy rates for QFs that are
entitled to a fixed price for capacity.
Although reasonable minds might
disagree about whether a fixed price for
capacity alone is sufficient
encouragement, combining one with a
variable price for energy would provide
at least some guaranteed revenue stream
with which to finance new
development.26 Indeed, much of the
Commission’s justification for
eliminating the fixed-price contract
option for energy rests on the
availability of a fixed-price contract
option for capacity.27 Commission
24 See Final Rule, 172 FERC ¶ 61,041 at P 340
(‘‘EIA data demonstrates that net generation of
energy by non-utility owned renewable resources in
the United States grew by almost 700% between
2005 and 2018.’’). Although independent power
producers, renewable or otherwise, within the RTO/
ISO markets are not entitled to fixed price contracts
for energy as a matter of law, they generally do rely
on alternative tools, such as commodity hedges, to
lock-in energy revenue streams. See, e.g., EEI
Comments at 36; sPower Comments at 12.
25 In the logical leap of the year, the Commission
notes that in some areas of the country, unspecified
resources are developed with a fixed-price contract
for capacity and a variable price for energy and,
separately, that renewables have grown nationwide
more than seven-fold between 2005 and 2018. Final
Rule, 172 FERC ¶ 61,041 at P 340. From those
disparate observations, the Commission concludes
that ‘‘renewable resources are able to acquire
financing even without the right to require longterm fixed energy rates.’’ Id. But nothing in the
record suggests that that phenomenal growth in
renewables was at all the result of that bifurcated
contract structure. That, it should be clear, is not
reasoned decisionmaking. Cf. Nat’l Ass’n of
Recycling Indus., Inc. v. Fed. Mar. Comm’n, 658
F.2d 816, 820 n.10 (D.C. Cir. 1980) (‘‘We do not
want, after all, blithely to compare apples and
oranges. Likewise, an agency should also avoid
unavailing comparisons of nonsubstitutes.’’); see
also Commissioner Slaughter Comments at 4
(noting the ‘‘widespread geographic differentiation’’
in renewable energy progress and ‘‘barriers to
independent renewable energy-based power
producers’’).
26 See, e.g., SEIA Comments at 29 (‘‘While
securing financing based on an As-Available Energy
rate and a fixed capacity rate may be a rare
possibility in a few sub-markets across the country,
as Mr. Shem explains, it certainly is not the case
in any state that does not participate in an ISO/RTO
market.’’).
27 See Final Rule, 172 FERC ¶ 61,041 at P 36
(‘‘This assertion that the Commission has
eliminated fixed rates for QFs is not correct . . . .
The NOPR thus made clear: under the proposed
revisions to § 292.304(d), a QF would continue to
be entitled to a contract with avoided capacity costs
calculated and fixed at the time the LEO is
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
precedent, however, permits utilities to
offer a capacity rate of zero to QFs when
the utility does not need incremental
capacity.28 That means that, as a result
of this Final Rule, QF developers will
face the very real prospect of not
receiving any fixed revenue stream,
whether for energy or capacity, in areas
where they also cannot secure hedging
products or other mechanisms needed
to finance a new QF.29 It is hard for me
to understand how the Commission can,
with a straight face, claim to be
encouraging QF development while at
the same time eliminating the
conditions necessary to develop QFs in
the regions where they are being built.30
13. The Commission sidesteps this
point in responding that PURPA does
not require that QFs be financeable.
That is true in a literal sense; nothing in
PURPA directs the Commission to
ensure that at least some QFs be
financeable. But it does require the
Commission to encourage their
development, which we have previously
equated with financeability.31 If the
Commission is going to abandon that
standard, it must then explain why what
is left of its regulations provides the
requisite encouragement—an
explanation that is lacking from this
Final Rule, notwithstanding the
Commission’s repeated assertions to the
contrary.
14. The Commission also does not
sufficiently explain how eliminating the
fixed-price contract requirement is
consistent with PURPA’s requirement
that rates ‘‘shall not discriminate
against’’ QFs.32 Vertically integrated
incurred.’’) (internal quotation marks omitted); id.
P 237 (‘‘The Commission stated that these fixed
capacity and variable energy payments have been
sufficient to permit the financing of significant
amounts of new capacity in the RTOs and ISOs.’’).
28 See, e.g., id. P 422 (citing to City of Ketchikan,
Alaska, 94 FERC ¶ 61,293, at 62,061 (2001)).
29 See, e.g., Resources for the Future Comments at
6; SEIA Comments at 30; Southeast Public Interest
Organizations Comments at 12.
30 See Public Interest Organizations Comments at
10–11 (‘‘Obviously, rules that have an effect of
discouraging QFs cannot be ’necessary to’
encouraging them.’’); see also Massachusetts
Attorney General Maura Healey Comments at 6
(‘‘This action may reduce investor confidence and
discourage future development. That outcome is a
negative one for the Commonwealth and its
ratepayers.’’).
31 See, e.g., Order No. 69, FERC Stats. & Regs.
¶ 30,128 at 30,880 (justifying the rule on the basis
of ‘‘the need for certainty with regard to return on
investment in new technologies’’); NOPR, 168 FERC
¶ 61,184 at P 63 (‘‘The Commission’s justification
for allowing QFs to fix their rate at the time of the
LEO for the entire term of a contract was that fixing
the rate provides certainty necessary for the QF to
obtain financing.’’).
32 16 U.S. Code § 824a–3(b)(2). Unlike provisions
of the Federal Power Act, PURPA prohibits any
discrimination against QFs, not just undue
discrimination. See ELCON Comments at 21–22;
PO 00000
Frm 00102
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
utilities effectively receive guaranteed
fixed-price contracts through their rights
to recover prudently incurred
investments. The equivalent right to
receive fixed-price contracts has to date
proved an integral element of the
Commission’s ability to satisfy PURPA’s
prohibition on discriminatory rates.33
15. And yet this Final Rule fails to
explain how eliminating the fixed-price
option is consistent with that
prohibition or, moreover, how
permitting QFs to receive variable
contract rates while vertically integrated
utilities receive fixed ones is consistent
with the Commission’s obligation to
promote QFs.34 Instead, the
Commission notes that, through socalled fuel adjustment clauses,
vertically integrated utilities’ rates
change as the price of fuel changes.35
The idea that those clauses, which
ensure that utilities recover a specific
variable cost (i.e., their cost of fuel), is
the same thing as having your entire
revenue exposed to variations in
prevailing market conditions is
hogwash. The presence of fuel
adjustment clauses in no way suggests
that vertically integrated utilities are
subject to anything remotely close to the
level of revenue variation contemplated
in this Final Rule.
16. Finally, the Commission fails to
explain why allegations of QF rates
exceeding a utility’s actual avoided cost
requires us to abandon the
Commission’s long-held principles
regarding certainty and financing.36 As
an initial matter, the Commission has
recognized that QF rates may exceed
actual avoided costs, but, at the same
time, recognized that avoided cost rates
might also turn out to be lower than the
electric utility’s avoided costs over the
course of the contract. The Commission
has reasoned that, ‘‘in the long run,
‘overestimations’ and ‘underestimations’
of avoided costs will balance out.’’ 37
However, when presented with a couple
allegations that avoided costs were
overestimated,38 the Commission now
concludes that that possibility suggests
it must abandon the fixed-energy rate
South Carolina Solar Business Alliance Comments
at 7–8; sPower Comments at 13.
33 See supra n.20; Commissioner Slaughter
Comments at 4.
34 Public Interest Organizations Comments at 51
(‘‘[L]imiting QFs to contracts providing no price
certainty for energy values, while non-QF
generation regularly obtains fixed price contracts
and utility-owned generation receives guaranteed
cost recovery from captive ratepayers, constitutes
discrimination.’’).
35 Final Rule, 172 FERC ¶ 61,041 at P 122.
36 See supra n.19.
37 Order No. 69, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 30,128 at
30,880.
38 Final Rule, 172 FERC ¶ 61,041 at PP 265, 268.
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
contract altogether. The Commission,
however, makes no effort to validate
these allegations,39 or assess whether
the overestimations of avoided cost
were, in fact, balanced out.40 It is
arbitrary and capricious to point to only
half the picture in abandoning a fortyyear-old principle.
ii. Rebuttable Presumption for Setting
Avoided Cost at LMP and Similar
Measures
17. I also do not support the
Commission’s decision to treat LMP or
other ‘‘competitive market prices’’ as a
presumptively reasonable measure of an
as-available avoided cost for energy.41
Liquid price signals can be useful and
transparent inputs and ought to be
considered in calculating an appropriate
avoided-cost figure. But considering
those price signals in setting avoided
cost is not the same thing as presuming
that LMP or similar measures are alone
sufficient to establish avoided cost.
Many regions of the country—often the
same regions where the debates about
PURPA are most heated—have not
established sufficiently competitive
markets. In these regions it is not clear
from the record that the prices in, for
example, a neighboring RTO, are a
representative measure of a utility’s
avoided cost. In those less competitive
markets, it simply does not make sense
to presume that LMP or other
‘‘competitive market prices’’ are a
representative measure of avoided cost,
rather than one of many criteria that
should go into that determination.42
18. For similar reasons, I share the
concern of many commenters that shortterm or spot prices, such as LMP, may
not reflect the long-term marginal
energy costs avoided by purchasing
utilities, especially outside of organized
39 Id.
PP 291, 293.
Commission is quick to point to ‘‘the
precipitous decline in natural gas prices’’ starting
in 2008 that may have caused QF contracts fixed
prior to that period to underestimate the actual cost
of energy. See, e.g., Final Rule, 172 FERC ¶ 61,041
at P 287). However, PURPA has been in place for
forty years, and the Commission does not wrestle
with the magnitude of potential savings conveyed
to consumers from the fixed-price energy contracts
that locked-in low rates for consumers during the
decades prior when natural gas prices were several
times higher. See Energy Information
Administration Total Energy, tbl. 9.10 (last viewed
July 15, 2020), https://www.eia.gov/totalenergy/
data/browser/.
41 Final Rule, 172 FERC ¶ 61,041 at PP 151, 189,
211.
42 Congress itself seems to have contemplated that
states would not rely solely on spot market prices
when establishing avoided cost. H.R. Rep. No. 95–
1750, at 7833 (1978) (‘‘In interpreting the term
‘incremental cost of alternative energy,’ the
conferees expect that the Commission and the states
may look beyond the cost of alternative sources
which are instantaneously available to the utility.’’).
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
40 The
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
markets.43 Although the Commission
revises the NOPR’s per se rule to be a
rebuttable presumption, it nevertheless
plows ahead with the conclusion that
LMP, and similar measures, reflect a
utility’s avoided cost of energy. Where
there is good reason to believe that those
measures do not actually reflect the
long-term value of energy that they are
supposed to represent, it makes no
sense to put the burden on QFs to prove
the point,44 rather than leaving the
burden with the proponents of using
such measures.
19. The Commission’s presumptive
approval of LMP and similar measures
is even more problematic when
combined with the decision to allow
utilities to eliminate the fixed-price
contract option. Following this Final
Rule, QFs may be reduced to relying
solely on some synthetic and highly
variable measure of what spot prices
should be in a competitive market based
on gas prices and heat rates, all while
the utilities whose costs the QF is
avoiding recovers an effectively
guaranteed rate potentially in excess of
this representative ‘‘competitive market
price.’’ I am not persuaded that this
approach will satisfy our obligation to
encourage QFs and to do so using rates
that are non-discriminatory across all
regions of the country.
B. Rebuttable Presumption 20 MW to 5
MW
20. Following the Energy Policy Act
of 2005, the Commission established a
rebuttable presumption that QFs with a
capacity greater than 20 MW operating
in RTOs and ISOs have nondiscriminatory access to competitive
markets, eliminating utilities’ must43 Final Rule, 172 FERC ¶ 61,041 at n.163; Hydro
Comments at 11; Southeast Public Interest
Organizations Comments at 19; NIPPC, CREA, REC,
and OSEIA Comments at 52, 55; Union of
Concerned Scientists Comments at 6. Take, for
example, the Commission’s approval of the MidColumbia market hub price as presumptively
reflecting a utility’s avoided cost for energy. See
Final Rule, 172 FERC ¶ 61,041 at PP 180, 189.
Notwithstanding explicit support for this approach
from the regulated utility industry, the Washington
Utilities and Transportation Commission which,
when addressing Puget Sound Energy’s plan to
increase wholesale purchases from the MidColumbia market ‘‘liquid hub’’ to 1,600 MW,
expressed a concern about the regulated utility’s
overreliance on such wholesale market pricing and
directed them to pursue an alternative plan to
eliminate this ‘‘excessive risk.’’ That is the exact
type of tension conveyed in the record—i.e, that
such competitive market prices may not accurately
reflect a utility’s avoided cost, as approved by
regulators. See Washington UTC, Acknowledgment
Letter Attachment, Puget Sound Energy’s 2017
Electric and Natural Gas Integrated Resource Plan,
Wash. UTC Docket Nos. UE–160918, UG–160919
(Revised June 19, 2018); see NIPPC, CREA, REC,
and OSEIA Comments at 56.
44 Final Rule, 172 FERC ¶ 61,041 at P 152.
PO 00000
Frm 00103
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
54739
purchase obligation from those
resources.45 The Final Rule reduces the
threshold for that presumption from 20
MW to 5 MW. 46 That is an
improvement over the NOPR, which—
without any support whatsoever—
proposed to lower that threshold to 1
MW.47 But, even so, the reduced 5 MW
threshold is unsupported by the record
and inadequately justified in today’s
Final Rule.
21. When it originally established the
20 MW threshold, the Commission
pointed to an array of barriers that
prevented resources below that level
from having truly non-discriminatory
access to RTO/ISO markets. Those
barriers included complications
associated with accessing the
transmission system through the
distribution system (a common
occurrence for such small resources),
challenges with reaching distant offtakers, as well as ‘‘jurisdictional
differences, pancaked delivery rates,
and additional administrative
procedures’’ that complicate those
resources’ ability to participate in those
markets on a level playing field.48 In
just the last few years, the Commission
has recognized the persistence of those
barriers ‘‘that gave rise to the rebuttable
presumption that smaller QFs lack
nondiscriminatory access to markets.’’ 49
22. Nevertheless, the Final Rule
abandons the 20 MW threshold based
on the conclusory assertion that ‘‘it is
reasonable to presume that access to
RTO/ISO markets has improved’’ and it
is, therefore, ‘‘appropriate to update the
presumption.’’ 50 No doubt markets have
improved. But a borderline-truism about
maturing markets does not explain how
the barriers arrayed against small
resources have dissipated, why it is
reasonable to ‘‘presume’’ that the
remaining barriers do not inhibit nondiscriminatory access, or why 5 MW is
45 New PURPA Section 210(m) Regulations
Applicable to Small Power Production and
Cogeneration Facilities, Order No. 688, 117 FERC
¶ 61,078, at P 72 (2006), order on reh’g, Order No.
688–A, 119 FERC ¶ 61,305 (2007), aff’d sub nom.
Am. Forest & Paper Ass’n v. FERC, 550 F.3d 1179
(D.C. Cir. 2008); see 16 U.S.C. § 824a–3(m).
46 Final Rule, 172 FERC ¶ 61,041 at P 625.
47 NOPR, 168 FERC ¶ 61,184 at P 126.
48 Order No. 688–A, 119 FERC ¶ 61,305 at PP 96,
103.
49 E.g., N. States Power Co., 151 FERC ¶ 61,110,
at P 34 (2015).
50 Final Rule, 172 FERC ¶ 61,041 at P 629 (‘‘Over
the last 15 years, the RTO/ISO markets have
matured, market participants have gained a better
understanding of the mechanics of such markets
and, as a result, we find that it is reasonable to
presume that access to the RTO/ISO markets has
improved and that it is appropriate to update the
presumption for smaller production facilities.’’).
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
54740
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 / Rules and Regulations
an appropriate new threshold for that
presumption.
23. Instead of any such evidence, the
Final Rule notes that the Commission
uses the 5 MW as a demarcating line for
other rules applying to small resources.
Specifically, it points to the fact that
resources below 5 MW can use a ‘‘fasttrack’’ interconnection process, whereas
larger ones must use the large generator
interconnection procedures.51 But the
fact that the Commission used 5 MW as
the cut off in another context hardly
shows that it is the right cut off to use
in this context.
24. Lacking substantial evidence to
support the 5 MW threshold, the
Commission falls back on a deferential
standard of review.52 But while judicial
review of agency policymaking is
deferential, it is not toothless. The same
cases on which the Commission relies
require that, when an agency’s policy
reversal ‘‘rests upon factual findings
that contradict those which underlay its
prior policy,’’ the agency must ‘‘provide
a more detailed justification than what
would suffice for a new policy created
on a blank slate.’’ 53 That is because
reasoned decisionmaking requires that,
when an agency changes course, it must
provide ‘‘a reasoned explanation . . .
for disregarding facts and circumstances
that underlay or were engendered by the
prior policy.’’ 54 For the foregoing
reasons, the Commission has failed to
produce any such explanation, making
its change of course arbitrary and
capricious.
III. Environmental Review Under the
National Environmental Policy Act
25. In contrast to the Commission’s
crowing over the significance of its
PURPA overhaul, the Final Rule
51 Id.
P 630.
P 637 (citing FCC v. Fox Television, 556
U.S. 502, 515 (2009), for the proposition that an
agency ‘‘need not demonstrate to a court’s
satisfaction that the reasons for the new policy are
better than the reasons for the old one; it suffices
that the new policy is permissible under the statute,
that there are good reasons for it, and that the
agency believes it to be better, which the conscious
change of course adequately indicates.’’).
53 Fox Television, 556 U.S. at 515; Advanced
Energy Economy Comments at 6.
54 Fox Television, 556 U.S. at 516; Advanced
Energy Economy Comments at 6–7.
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with RULES2
52 Id.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:20 Sep 01, 2020
Jkt 250001
describes the changes adopted as merely
corrective and clarifying in nature when
it comes to conducting an
environmental review.55 In particular,
the Commission contends that ‘‘the
changes adopted in this final rule are
required to ensure continued future
compliance of the PURPA Regulations
with PURPA, based on the changed
circumstances found by the Commission
in this final rule.’’ 56 In other words,
because the Commission believes that
the changes adopted are necessary to
conform with the statute, they are mere
corrective changes, which, in turn,
qualifies them for the categorical
exemption from any environmental
review under NEPA, or so the argument
goes.
26. But by that logic, any Commission
action needed to comply with our
various statutory mandates—whether
‘‘just and reasonable’’ or the ‘‘public
interest’’—would be deemed corrective
in nature and, therefore, excluded from
environmental review. The
Commission, however, fails to point to
any evidence suggesting that is what the
Council on Environmental Quality
contemplated when it allowed for
categorical exemptions.
IV. The Way To Revise PURPA Is To
Create More Competition, Not Less
27. It didn’t have to be this way.
When Congress reformed PURPA in the
2005 Energy Policy Act amendments, it
indicated an unmistakable preference
for using market competition as the offramp for utilities seeking relief from
their PURPA obligations.57 Those
reforms directed the Commission to
excuse utilities from those obligations
where QFs had non-discriminatory
access to RTO/ISO markets or other
sufficiently competitive constructs.58
28. This record contains numerous
comments explaining how the
Commission could use those
amendments as a way to ‘‘modernize’’
55 Under the National Environmental Policy Act
(NEPA), the Commission must consider whether its
action associated with rulemakings will have a
significant impact on the environment. See 42
U.S.C. 4321 et seq.
56 Final Rule, 172 FERC ¶ 61,041 at P 722.
57 16 U.S.C. § 824a–3(m).
58 See Order No. 688, 117 FERC ¶ 61,078 at P 8.
PO 00000
Frm 00104
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 9990
PURPA in a manner that both promotes
actual competition and reflects
Congress’s unambiguous intent.59 For
example, in a white paper released prior
to the NOPR, the National Association
of Regulatory Utility Commissioners
(NARUC) urged the Commission to give
meaning to the 2005 amendments by
establishing criteria by which a
vertically integrated utility outside of an
RTO or ISO could apply to terminate the
must-purchase obligation if it conducts
sufficiently competitive solicitations for
energy and capacity.60 Other groups,
including representatives of QF
interests, submitted additional
comments on how an approach along
those lines might work.61 Several parties
commented on those proposals.62
It is a shame that the Commission has
elected to administratively gut its longstanding PURPA implementation
regime, rather than pursuing reform
rooted in PURPA section 210(m), such
as the NARUC proposal. Pursuing an
option along those lines could have
produced a durable, consensus solution
to the issues before us. I continue to
believe that the way to modernize
PURPA is to promote real competition,
not to gut the provisions that the
Commission has relied on for decades
out of frustration that Congress has
repeatedly failed to repeal the statute
itself.
For these reasons, I respectfully dissent in
part.
Richard Glick,
Commissioner.
[FR Doc. 2020–15902 Filed 9–1–20; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6717–01–P
59 See Advanced Energy Economy Comments at
13; Industrial Energy Consumers Comments at 13–
14; EPSA Comments at 16.
60 National Association of Regulatory Utility
Commissioners Supplemental Comments, Docket
No. AD16–16–00, Attach. A, at 8 (Oct. 17, 2018);
id. (proposing the Commission’s Edgar-Allegheny
criteria as a basis for evaluating whether a proposal
was adequately competitive).
61 See, e.g., SEIA Supplemental Comments,
Docket No. AD16–16–000 (Aug. 28, 2019).
62 See, e.g., Advanced Energy Economy
Comments at 12; APPA Comments at 29; Colorado
Independent Energy Comments at 7; ELCON
Comments at 19; Public Interest Organizations
Comments at 90; SEIA Comments at 24; Xcel
Comments at 11.
E:\FR\FM\02SER2.SGM
02SER2
Agencies
[Federal Register Volume 85, Number 171 (Wednesday, September 2, 2020)]
[Rules and Regulations]
[Pages 54638-54740]
From the Federal Register Online via the Government Publishing Office [www.gpo.gov]
[FR Doc No: 2020-15902]
[[Page 54637]]
Vol. 85
Wednesday,
No. 171
September 2, 2020
Part II
Department of Energy
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
18 CFR Parts 292 and 375
Qualifying Facility Rates and Requirements Implementation Issues Under
the Public Utility Regulatory Policies Act of 1978; Final Rule
Federal Register / Vol. 85 , No. 171 / Wednesday, September 2, 2020 /
Rules and Regulations
[[Page 54638]]
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
DEPARTMENT OF ENERGY
Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
18 CFR Parts 292 and 375
[Docket Nos. RM19-15-000 and AD16-16-000; Order No. 872]
Qualifying Facility Rates and Requirements Implementation Issues
Under the Public Utility Regulatory Policies Act of 1978
AGENCY: Federal Energy Regulatory Commission.
ACTION: Final rule.
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
SUMMARY: In this Order, the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission issues
its final rule approving certain revisions to its regulations
implementing sections 201 and 210 of the Public Utility Regulatory
Policies Act of 1978 (PURPA). These changes will enable the Commission
to continue to fulfill its statutory obligations under sections 201 and
210 of PURPA.
DATES: This rule is effective December 31, 2020.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: Lawrence R. Greenfield (Legal
Information), Office of the General Counsel, Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission, 888 First Street NE, Washington, DC 20426, (202) 502-6415,
[email protected].
Helen Shepherd (Technical Information), Office of Energy Market
Regulation, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, 888 First Street NE,
Washington, DC 20426, (202) 502-6176, [email protected].
Thomas Dautel (Technical Information), Office of Energy Policy and
Innovation, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, 888 First Street NE,
Washington, DC 20426, (202) 502-6196, [email protected].
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION:
Table of Contents
Paragraph
Nos.
I. Introduction............................................. 1
II. Overview................................................ 5
A. The Commission's PURPA Regulations, as Revised by 6
This Final Rule, Continue To Encourage the Development
of QFs Within the Requirements of PURPA's Statutory
Limitations............................................
1. Avoided Cost Cap on QF Rates..................... 13
2. Limitation on Small Power Production Facilities 17
Located at the Same ``Site''.......................
3. Termination of Purchase Obligation for QFs With 18
Nondiscriminatory Access to Certain Competitive
Markets............................................
4. Final Rule's Updating of the PURPA Regulations... 20
B. The Final Rule Ensures That the Commission's 28
Implementation of PURPA Continues To Benefit QFs,
Purchasing Electric Utilities, and Electric Consumers..
C. The Commission Is Not Eliminating Fixed Rate Pricing 35
for QFs, But Rather Is Giving States the Flexibility To
Require the Same Variable Energy Rate/Fixed Capacity
Rate Construct That Applies Throughout the Electric
Industry...............................................
D. The Rate Changes Implemented by This Final Rule Put 39
QF Rates on the Same Footing as Electric Utility Rates
and Are Not Discriminatory.............................
E. The PURPA Compliance Issues Raised by Some Commenters 42
Are Outside the Scope of This Rulemaking Proceeding....
III. Background............................................. 47
A. Passage of PURPA in 1978 and the Commission's 47
Promulgation of Its PURPA Regulations in 1980..........
B. Circumstances Leading to the Commission's Re- 51
evaluation of the PURPA Regulations and the Issuance of
the NOPR...............................................
C. Summary of Changes to the PURPA Regulations 56
Implemented by This Final Rule.........................
IV. Discussion.............................................. 67
A. General Legal Standards Under PURPA.................. 67
1. Encouragement of QFs............................. 68
a. Comments..................................... 68
b. Commission Determination..................... 70
2. Discrimination................................... 79
a. Comments..................................... 79
b. Commission Determination..................... 82
3. Unlawful Delegation and the Role of Nonregulated 89
Electric Utilities.................................
a. Comments..................................... 89
b. Commission Determination..................... 93
B. QF Rates............................................. 96
1. Overview......................................... 96
2. Use of Competitive Market Prices To Set As- 103
Available Avoided Cost Rates.......................
a. NOPR Proposal................................ 104
b. Comments..................................... 107
c. Commission Determination..................... 114
3. LMP as a Permissible Rate for Certain As- 124
Available Avoided Cost Rates.......................
a. NOPR Proposal................................ 124
b. Comments..................................... 129
i. Comments in Opposition................... 129
(a) Utilizing Western EIM To Establish 137
Avoided Costs..............................
ii. Comments in Support..................... 138
(a) Utilizing Western EIM To Establish 145
Avoided Costs..............................
iii. Comments in Support With Requested 146
Modifications/Clarifications...............
c. Commission Determination..................... 151
i. Arguments Against the NOPR Proposal...... 155
ii. Requests for Modification or 173
Clarification of the NOPR..................
iii. Western EIM............................ 177
4. Use of Market Hub Prices as a Permissible Rate 180
for Certain As-Available QF Energy Sales...........
a. NOPR Proposal................................ 180
b. Comments..................................... 182
i. Comments in Support...................... 182
ii. Comments in Opposition.................. 184
[[Page 54639]]
iii. Commission Determination............... 189
c. Proposed Modifications....................... 195
i. Comments................................. 195
ii. Commission Determination................ 200
5. Use of Formulas Based on Natural Gas Prices To 203
Establish a Permissible Rate for Certain As-
Available QF Energy Sales..........................
a. NOPR Proposal................................ 203
b. Comments..................................... 206
c. Commission Determination..................... 211
6. Permitting the Energy Rate Component of a 217
Contract To Be Fixed at the Time of the LEO Using
Forecasted Values of the Estimated Stream of Market
Revenues...........................................
a. Comments..................................... 219
b. Commission Determination..................... 227
7. Providing for Variable Energy Rates in QF 232
Contracts..........................................
a. Background................................... 232
b. NOPR Proposal................................ 234
c. General Comments on the NOPR Proposal........ 245
i. Comments in Support of NOPR Proposal..... 245
ii. Comments in Opposition to NOPR Proposal. 248
iii. Commission Determination............... 253
d. Whether the Current Approach Has Resulted in 265
Payments to QFs in Excess of Avoided Costs.....
i. Comments in Support of NOPR Proposal..... 265
ii. Comments in Opposition to NOPR Proposal. 272
iii. Commission Determination............... 283
e. Whether the Proposed Change Would Violate the 294
Statutory Requirement That the PURPA
Regulations Encourage QFs......................
i. Comments................................. 294
i. Commission Determination................. 295
f. Discrimination............................... 297
i. Comments in Support of NOPR Proposal..... 297
ii. Comments in Opposition to NOPR Proposal. 298
iii. Commission Determination............... 302
g. Effect of Variable Energy Rates on Financing. 304
i. Comments in Support of the NOPR Proposal. 304
ii. Comments in Opposition to the NOPR 312
Proposal...................................
iii. Commission Determination............... 335
h. Other Claimed Benefits of Fixed Avoided Cost 350
Energy Rates...................................
i. Comments................................. 350
ii. Commission Determination................ 351
i. Potential Modifications to NOPR Proposal..... 354
i. Comments................................. 354
ii. Commission Determination................ 357
8. Consideration of Competitive Solicitations To 361
Determine Avoided Costs............................
a. NOPR Proposal................................ 361
b. Comments..................................... 368
i. Comments in Opposition................... 368
ii. Comments in Support..................... 375
iii. Comments Requesting Modifications/ 383
Clarifications.............................
(a) Requests for Clarification and/or 383
Separate Proceedings.......................
(b) Requests Regarding Proposed Criteria.... 390
(c) Other Requests.......................... 400
c. Commission Determination..................... 411
i. Requests for Clarification and/or 415
Separate Proceedings.......................
ii. Proposed Criteria....................... 420
iii. Other Requests......................... 439
C. Relief from Purchase Obligation in Competitive Retail 442
Markets................................................
1. NOPR Proposal.................................... 442
2. Comments......................................... 444
3. Commission Determination......................... 456
D. Evaluation of Whether QFs Are at Separate Sites...... 458
1. Rebuttable Presumption of Separate Sites......... 458
a. NOPR Proposal................................ 458
b. Commission Determination..................... 466
c. Need for Reform.............................. 470
i. Comments................................. 470
ii. Commission Determination................ 472
d. Site Definition.............................. 473
i. Comments................................. 473
ii. Commission Determination................ 476
e. Distance Between Facilities.................. 482
i. Comments................................. 482
ii. Commission Determination................ 490
f. Factors...................................... 497
[[Page 54640]]
i. Comments................................. 497
ii. Commission Determination................ 508
g. Exemptions................................... 512
i. Comments................................. 512
ii. Commission Determination................ 514
2. Electrical Generating Equipment.................. 515
a. NOPR Proposal................................ 515
b. Comments..................................... 518
c. Commission Determination..................... 521
E. QF Certification Process............................. 525
1. NOPR Proposal.................................... 525
2. Comments......................................... 530
3. Commission Determination......................... 547
F. Corresponding Changes to the FERC Form No. 556....... 570
1. NOPR Proposal.................................... 570
2. Comments......................................... 577
3. Commission Determination......................... 584
G. PURPA Section 210(m) Rebuttable Presumption of 597
Nondiscriminatory Access to Markets....................
1. PURPA Section 210(m) Implementation.............. 597
a. NOPR Proposal................................ 597
b. Comments in Opposition....................... 602
i. Insufficient Evidentiary Support......... 603
ii. Administrative Burden and Complex Market 611
Rules......................................
c. Comments in Support.......................... 614
d. Comments Requesting Modifications/ 617
Clarifications.................................
e. Commission Determination..................... 624
2. Reliance on RFPs and Liquid Market Hubs To 648
Terminate Purchase Obligation Under PURPA Section
210(m).............................................
a. NOPR Discussion.............................. 648
b. Comments..................................... 651
i. Comments in Opposition................... 651
ii. Comments in Support..................... 655
c. Commission Determination..................... 659
H. Legally Enforceable Obligation....................... 663
1. NOPR Proposal.................................... 663
2. Comments......................................... 666
a. Comments in Opposition....................... 666
b. Comments in Support.......................... 673
c. Comments Requesting Modification............. 676
i. Studies.................................. 677
ii. Commercial Viability.................... 679
iii. Financial Viability.................... 681
iv. Rejecting QF Purchases and Expanded 683
Curtailment Rights.........................
3. Commission Determination......................... 684
V. Information Collection Statement......................... 697
VI. Environmental Analysis.................................. 702
A. Comments............................................. 703
B. Commission Determination............................. 710
1. No EIS or EA is Required......................... 712
a. There Is No Project That Defines the Scope 712
and Limits of QF Development...................
b. A Categorical Exclusion Applies.............. 720
i. Changes That Are Clarifying in Nature.... 721
ii. Changes That Are Corrective in Nature... 722
iii. Changes That Are Procedural in Nature.. 727
2. The NEPA Analysis for Promulgation of the 728
Original PURPA Regulations in 1980 Cannot Be
Replicated Here....................................
3. This Proceeding Does Not Trigger Any ESA 737
Consultation Requirement...........................
VII. Regulatory Flexibility Act Certification............... 743
VIII. Document Availability................................. 750
IX. Effective Dates and Congressional Notification.......... 753
I. Introduction
1. In this Order, the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
(Commission) issues its final rule approving certain revisions to its
regulations (PURPA Regulations) \1\ implementing sections 201 and 210
of the Public Utility Regulatory Policies Act of 1978 (PURPA).\2\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1\ 18 CFR part 292 (2019). In connection with the revisions to
the PURPA Regulations, the Commission also is revising its
delegation of authority to Commission staff in 18 CFR pt. 375.
\2\ 16 U.S.C. 796(17)-(18), 824a-3.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
2. On September 19, 2019, the Commission issued a notice of
proposed rulemaking (NOPR) proposing to modify its PURPA
Regulations.\3\ Those regulations were promulgated in 1980 and have
been modified in only specific respects since then. Approximately 130
separate comments were submitted in response to the NOPR,\4\ several of
which were submitted on behalf of multiple parties. In total, over
1,600 pages of comments were submitted, and in addition thousands of
pages of exhibits
[[Page 54641]]
were attached to the comments. The entities that filed comments are
listed in Appendix A. This final rule addresses comments received in
response to the NOPR.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\3\ Qualifying Facility Rates and Requirements Implementation
Issues Under the Public Utility Regulatory Policies Act of 1978, 168
FERC ] 61184 (2019) (NOPR).
\4\ See Appendix for list of commenters.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
3. We largely adopt the NOPR proposals. However, this final rule
makes certain modifications to the NOPR proposals, as further discussed
below.
4. Given the Commission's expressed intent in the NOPR to propose
revisions to the PURPA Regulations that more closely adhere to the
goals and terms of PURPA,\5\ we considered comments regarding whether
these proposals are consistent with the requirements of PURPA. Based on
that review and further consideration, we adopt the following changes
to the proposals in the NOPR, among certain others described below:
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\5\ NOPR, 168 FERC ] 61,184 at P 31.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
We establish a rebuttable presumption, rather than a per
se rule, that locational marginal prices (LMPs) may reflect a
purchasing electric utility's avoided energy costs;
We provide that any competitive solicitations used to
establish avoided capacity costs must adhere to the Commission's
Allegheny \6\ standard for evaluating competitive solicitations;
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\6\ Allegheny Energy Supply Co., LLC, 108 FERC ] 61,082, at P 18
(2004) (Allegheny).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
We do not adopt the proposed rule permitting states with
retail competition to allow relief from the purchase obligation but
instead clarify that the Commission's existing PURPA Regulations
already require that states, to the extent practicable, must account
for reduced loads in setting QF capacity rates;
We clarify terminology we used in the NOPR relating to the
determination of whether small power production facilities are separate
facilities to focus not on whether they are separate facilities, but
rather to mirror the statutory language and thus focus on whether they
are at ``the same site'';
We clarify in the regulations that protests may be made to
initial self-certifications and applications for Commission
certification, but only to self-recertifications and applications for
Commission recertification making substantive changes to the existing
certification;
We identify additional factors that can be considered for
small power production qualifying facilities (QFs) located more than
one but less than 10 miles apart, such as evidence of shared control
systems, common permitting and land leasing, and shared step-up
transformers;
We revise the regulations to lower the rebuttable
presumption of small power production QFs' nondiscriminatory access to
5 MW, rather than 1 MW as proposed in the NOPR, and include factors
that a small power production QF sized greater than 5 MW could rely on
to rebut the presumption that it has nondiscriminatory access to
markets defined in PURPA sections 210(m)(1); and
We revise the proposed requirements to establish a legally
enforceable obligation (LEO) to provide that with regard to the issue
of obtaining permits, QFs need only have applied for all required
permits, instead of being required to have already obtained those
permits.
II. Overview
5. Before discussing each of the individual changes to the PURPA
Regulations adopted herein, this final rule first addresses certain
overall themes raised in the comments on the NOPR, both those
supporting the NOPR and those opposing.
A. The Commission's PURPA Regulations, as Revised by This Final Rule,
Continue To Encourage the Development of QFs Within the Requirements of
PURPA's Statutory Limitations
6. PURPA section 210(a) requires that the Commission prescribe
rules that it determines necessary to encourage the development of
qualifying small power production facilities and cogeneration
facilities.
7. The bulk of the criticism of the Commission's proposed rule
changes is based on a widespread misunderstanding, as reflected in the
comments on the NOPR, that PURPA and the PURPA Regulations were
intended to encourage QF development without any limit, and that the
rule changes proposed in the NOPR improperly reduce or even eliminate
encouragement in contravention of the statute. Those commenters
opposing the NOPR proposals argue that the Commission has determined,
in contravention of the statute, that there no longer is a need to
encourage QFs, or eliminated any provision that provides such
encouragement.\7\ Many of the commenters supporting the changes
proposed in the NOPR applaud the Commission for eliminating what they
argue amounts to an improper subsidy of QFs.\8\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\7\ See, e.g., Biological Diversity Comments at 14; ConEd
Development Comments at 2; Harvard Electricity Law Comments at 4;
New England Small Hydro Comments at 4; NIPPC, CREIA, REC, and OSEIA
Comments at 3, 21, 28; Public Interest Organizations Comments at 9,
39; Solar Energy Industries Comments at 4; Southeast Public Interest
Organizations Comments at 17.
\8\ See Competitive Enterprise Institute Comments at 3;
Progressive Policy Institute Comments at 1-2; SBE Council Comments
at 2; Mr. Moore Comments at 1-2.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
8. Neither side is correct about either what PURPA and the current
PURPA Regulations require, or the basis for the changes to the PURPA
Regulations proposed in the NOPR.
9. As an initial matter, PURPA was not a directive to the
Commission to encourage QF development without limitation. Indeed, as
explained below, Congress included several limitations in PURPA. By
reading the statute as a whole, and the PURPA Regulations as a whole as
revised by this final rule, it is clear that the PURPA Regulations
continue to encourage the development of QFs consistent with PURPA.\9\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\9\ 16 U.S.C. 824a-3(a).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
10. We also emphasize that we do not by this final rule change
other elements to the Commission's existing PURPA Regulations that
continue to encourage QF development. These elements include, but are
not limited to, rules that: (1) Require electric utilities to provide
backup electric energy to QFs on a non-discriminatory basis and at just
and reasonable rates; (2) require electric utilities to interconnect
with QFs; and (3) provide exemptions to QFs from many provisions of the
Federal Power Act (FPA) and state laws governing utility rates and
financial organization.\10\ These provisions encourage the development
of QFs by relieving them of certain regulatory burdens otherwise
imposed on sellers of power and ensure they can operate their
facilities. Moreover, we stress that, besides the changes to the PURPA
Regulations regarding applications to terminate a purchasing electric
utility's mandatory purchase obligation under PURPA section 210(m) (see
infra section IV.G), nothing in this final rule eliminates QFs' rights
to sell electric energy or capacity as provided under PURPA.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\10\ See 18 CFR 292.303(c), 292.305, 292.601-02.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
11. As discussed in greater detail below, while PURPA provided for
the encouragement of cogeneration and small power production, PURPA
also provided that the Commission could not prescribe a rule that
provided for ``a rate which exceeds the incremental cost to the
electric utility of alternative electric energy.'' \11\ Furthermore,
PURPA requires the Commission to ``insure'' that the resulting rates
``shall be just and reasonable to the electric consumers of
[[Page 54642]]
the electric utility and in the public interest[.]'' \12\ Likewise,
while PURPA provided for the encouragement of small power production,
PURPA also limited the facilities which could be encouraged to those
facilities with no more than 80 MW power production capacity at the
same site.\13\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\11\ Compare id. with 16 U.S.C. 824a-3(b).
\12\ 16 U.S.C. 824a-3(b)(1).
\13\ Compare 16 U.S.C. 824a-3(a) with 16 U.S.C. 796(17)(A)(ii).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
12. Nothing in the text of PURPA requires the establishment of a
subsidy for QFs. This point was confirmed in the Conference Report
accompanying PURPA's passage: ``The provisions of this section are not
intended to require the rate payers of a utility to subsidize
cogenerators or small power producers.'' \14\ Congress thus structured
PURPA both specifically to give effect to its intent that QFs not be
subsidized and also to impose other mandatory limits on the
Commission's ability to encourage QFs that are relevant to this final
rule, as briefly summarized below.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\14\ H.R. Rep. No. 95-1750, at 98 (1978) (Conf. Rep.).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
1. Avoided Cost Cap on QF Rates
13. PURPA section 210(b) sets out the standards governing the rates
purchasing utilities must pay to QFs.\15\ Sections 210(b)(1) and (b)(2)
provide that QF rates ``shall be just and reasonable to the electric
consumers of the electric utility and in the public interest'' and
``shall not discriminate against qualifying cogenerators or qualifying
small power producers.'' \16\ After establishing these standards,
Congress then placed, in the final sentence of section 210(b), a cap on
the level of the rates utilities could be required to pay QFs: ``No
such rule prescribed under subsection (a) shall provide for a rate
which exceeds the incremental cost to the electric utility of
alternative electric energy.'' \17\ As the Conference Report for PURPA
explains:
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\15\ 16 U.S.C. 824a-3(b).
\16\ Id.
\17\ Id. (emphasis added). The statute defines an electric
utility's ``incremental costs'' as ``the cost to the electric
utility of the electric energy which, but for the purchase from such
cogenerator or small power producer, such utility would generate or
purchase from another source.'' 16 U.S.C. 824a-3(d); see also 18 CFR
292.101(b)(6) (implementing same and defining such ``incremental
costs'' as ``avoided costs'').
[T]he utility would not be required to purchase electric energy
from a qualifying cogeneration or small power production facility at
a rate which exceeds the lower of the rate described above, namely a
rate which is just and reasonable to consumers of the utility, in
the public interest, and nondiscriminatory, or the incremental cost
of alternate electric energy. This limitation on the rates which may
be required in purchasing from a cogenerator or small power producer
is meant to act as an upper limit on the price at which utilities
can be required under this section to purchase electric energy.\18\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\18\ Conf. Rep. at 98 (emphasis added).
14. This upper limit on QF rates established in section 210(b),
equal to a purchasing utility's incremental costs, commonly called
``avoided costs,'' implements Congress's intent that QFs not be
subsidized. It ensures that the purchasing utility cannot be required
to pay more for power purchased from a QF than it would otherwise pay
to generate the power itself or to purchase power from a third party.
15. Consistent with the statutory standard, when the Commission
issued its PURPA Regulations in 1980, it set the rates for QFs at, but
not above, the statutorily defined incremental or avoided cost of
alternative electric energy.\19\ The PURPA Regulations applied this
limitation generally to QF rates, without distinguishing between as-
available energy \20\ and the fixed energy and capacity rate option
applicable to long-term contracts or other legally enforceable
obligations.\21\ In either case, though, the PURPA Regulations
essentially capped the rate paid to QFs at the purchasing electric
utility's avoided costs.\22\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\19\ Compare 16 U.S.C. 824a-3(b) & (d) with 18 CFR
292.101(b)(6), 292.304(a)(2) & (b)(2).
\20\ 18 CFR 292.304(d)(1).
\21\ 18 CFR 292.304(d)(2) (providing QFs the right to elect
avoided costs calculated at the time of delivery or avoided costs
calculated at the time the obligation is incurred). In this final
rule, we refer to the QF's option for avoided costs calculated at
the time the obligation is incurred as the fixed energy and capacity
rate option. 18 CFR 292.304(d)(2).
\22\ The regulations, however, also allowed both for negotiated
rates that differed from the rates that would otherwise be
applicable, see 18 CFR 292.301(b), and for rates to be set based on
estimates of avoided costs even though such rates might differ from
avoided costs at the time of delivery. See 18 CFR 292.304(b)(5).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
16. Order No. 69, in which the Commission promulgated the PURPA
Regulations,\23\ makes clear that the Commission also recognized that
allowing the option for a fixed energy and capacity rate option for
long-term contracts or other legally enforceable obligations could
result in a rate that, at times, exceeded incremental or avoided cost
of alternative electric energy. The Commission acknowledged in this
regard that some commenters had asserted that, ``if the avoided cost of
energy at the time it is supplied is less than the price provided in
the contract or obligation, the purchasing utility would be required to
pay a rate for purchases that would subsidize the qualifying facility
at the expense of the utility's other ratepayers.'' \24\ In response,
the Commission stated that it ``recognize[d] this possibility, but is
cognizant that in other cases, the required rate will turn out to be
lower than the avoided cost at the time of purchase.'' \25\ The
Commission concluded that any over- and under-recoveries compared to
avoided cost ``will balance out'' and, based on this conclusion, found
that the fixed energy and capacity rate option applicable to long-term
contracts or other legally enforceable obligations did not violate the
statutory cap.\26\ But, to be clear, the option the Commission
implemented in 1980 was not based on any determination by the
Commission that the rates in QF contracts may routinely exceed avoided
costs in the ordinary course of events in order to encourage QFs.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\23\ Small Power Production and Cogeneration Facilities;
Regulations Implementing Section 210 of the Public Utility
Regulatory Policies Act of 1978, Order No. 69, FERC Stats. & Regs. ]
30,128, at 30,880 (cross-referenced 10 FERC ] 61,150), order on
reh'g, Order No. 69-A, FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 30,160 (1980) (cross-
referenced at 11 FERC ] 61,166), aff'd in part & vacated in part sub
nom. Am. Elec. Power Serv. Corp. v. FERC, 675 F.2d 1226 (D.C. Cir.
1982), rev'd in part sub nom. Am. Paper Inst., Inc. v. Am. Elec.
Power Serv. Corp., 461 U.S. 402 (1983) (API).
\24\ Order No. 69, FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 30,128 at 30,880.
\25\ Id.
\26\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
2. Limitation on Small Power Production Facilities Located at the Same
``Site''
17. Another way in which Congress set boundaries on the
Commission's ability to encourage development of QFs was to define
small power production facilities, one of the categories of generators
that under the statute is to be encouraged. The definition of small
power production facilities applies to almost all renewable resources
that wish to be QFs, requiring that those facilities have ``a power
production capacity which, together with any other facilities located
at the same site (as determined by the Commission), is not greater than
80 megawatts.'' \27\ In order to comply with this statutory requirement
that the capacity of all small power production facilities ``located at
the same site'' cannot exceed 80 MW, the Commission is required to
define what constitutes a ``site.'' The Commission determined in 1980
that, essentially, those facilities that are owned by the same or
affiliated entities and using the same energy resource should be deemed
to be at the same site ``if they are located within one mile of the
facility for which
[[Page 54643]]
qualification is sought.'' \28\ This definition, known as the ``one-
mile rule,'' interpreted Congress's limitation of 80 MW located at the
same site to apply to just those affiliated small power production
qualifying facilities located within one mile of each other.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\27\ 16 U.S.C. 796(17)(A)(ii).
\28\ 18 CFR 292.204(a)(ii).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
3. Termination of Purchase Obligation for QFs With Nondiscriminatory
Access to Certain Competitive Markets
18. Finally, Congress amended PURPA in 2005 to further limit the
statute. Congress amended PURPA section 210 to add section 210(m),
which provides for termination of the requirement that an electric
utility enter into a new obligation or contract to purchase from a QF
if the QF has nondiscriminatory access to certain defined types of
markets.\29\ This amendment reflected Congress's judgment that non-
discriminatory access to these markets provided adequate encouragement
for those QFs.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\29\ See 16 U.S.C. 824a-3(m).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
19. Congress directed the Commission to implement this requirement,
which it did in Order No. 688. In that order, the Commission identified
certain markets in which utilities would no longer be subject to the
PURPA mandatory purchase obligation under PURPA section 210(m) because
certain QFs have nondiscriminatory access to such markets.\30\ Although
not required in the new PURPA section 210(m), the Commission
established a rebuttable presumption that a QF with a net power
production capacity at or below 20 MW does not have nondiscriminatory
access to such markets.\31\ In creating this rebuttable presumption,
the Commission found persuasive arguments that some QFs may not have
nondiscriminatory access to markets in light of their small size.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\30\ New PURPA Section 210(m) Regulations Applicable to Small
Power Production and Cogeneration Facilities, Order No. 688, 117
FERC ] 61,078, at PP 9-12 (2006), order on reh'g, Order No. 688-A,
119 FERC ] 61,305 (2007), aff'd sub nom. Am. Forest & Paper Ass'n v.
FERC, 550 F.3d 1179 (D.C. Cir. 2008).
\31\ 18 CFR 292.309(d)(1).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
4. Final Rule's Updating of the PURPA Regulations
20. In this final rule, we are amending the PURPA Regulations,
principally with regard to the three statutory provisions described
above, i.e.: (1) The avoided cost cap on QF rates; (2) the 80 MW
limitation applicable to the combined capacity of affiliated small
power production QFs located at the same site; and (3) the termination
of the mandatory purchase obligation for QFs with nondiscriminatory
access to certain markets. Contrary to commenters' assertions that the
Commission has determined that it no longer is necessary to encourage
QFs and therefore that the Commission is making these changes in an
impermissible attempt to undo PURPA,\32\ we are modifying the PURPA
Regulations based on demonstrated changes in circumstances since the
current PURPA Regulations were first adopted to ensure that the
regulations continue to comply with PURPA's statutory requirements
established by Congress.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\32\ Biomass Power Comments at 2; Biological Diversity at 12;
EPSA Comments at 6 (``[T]he NOPR changes `would effectively gut'
PURPA.''); NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 28-29; Public
Interest Groups Comments at 25 (``[T]he changes proposed in the NOPR
will gut PURPA-mandated measures to encourage QF development.'');
Solar Energy Industries Comments at 8-14.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
21. For example, as explained in more detail below, the
Commission's expectation expressed in 1980 that over- and under-
recovery in rates compared to avoided cost ``will balance out'' \33\
was critical to the Commission's determination in 1980 that the fixed
energy and capacity rate option applicable to long-term contracts or
other legally enforceable obligations did not violate the statutory
avoided cost cap on QF rates. However, record evidence now demonstrates
that this expectation no longer is necessarily accurate. The
Commission's change to the PURPA Regulations adopted in this final
rule, giving states the ability to require variable energy rates in
long-term contracts or other legally enforceable obligations, allows
the states to better ensure that QF rates are at, but do not exceed,
the statutory maximum rate established by Congress.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\33\ Order No. 69, FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 30,128 at 30,880.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
22. This change is important for purposes of compliance with
PURPA's statutory mandates. As explained below, setting QF rates at
avoided costs allows the Commission to comply with the statutory goals
of encouraging QFs and providing for nondiscriminatory rates while at
the same time ensuring that such rates are just and reasonable to
consumers and do not subsidize QFs. The record shows that on some
occasions long-term fixed QF rates were well above actual avoided
costs, thereby causing consumers to subsidize those QFs in
contravention of PURPA and the Commission's expectations.
23. Similarly, the changes implemented by the Commission in this
final rule to the one-mile rule are intended to better ensure
compliance with the statutory requirement that small power production
facilities located at the same site cannot exceed 80 MW. And, 15 years
after Congress added PURPA section 210(m), because the Commission can
now make the determination, described below, that smaller QFs have non-
discriminatory access to RTO/ISO markets, an update to the rebuttable
presumption regarding non-discriminatory access to those markets is
appropriate to better ensure compliance with the statute.
24. Some commenters incorrectly assert that the final rule
impermissibly revises the PURPA Regulations in a way that no longer
encourages QFs. PURPA section 210(a) provides not simply that the
Commission is to prescribe rules that encourage QFs, but rather that
the Commission is to ``prescribe, and from time to time thereafter
revise, such rules as it determines necessary to encourage'' QFs.
Carrying out Congress's directive to ``from time to time thereafter
revise'' the rules is at the heart of what the Commission is doing in
this final rule. Consistent with this directive, the Commission is
considering revisions to ``such rules as it determines necessary to''
encourage QFs in light of current industry circumstances.\34\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\34\ We view the revisions to our rules implementing PURPA that
we adopt in this final rule as consistent with Congress's explicit
directive that the Commission ``from time to time thereafter [to]
revise'' the rules. We do not view Congress as intending that the
Commission only ever consider the circumstances that existed in the
late 1970s and not current circumstances, 40 years later.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
25. The changes adopted in this final rule result from the need for
the PURPA Regulations to continue to comply with the directives
Congress established when it enacted PURPA in 1978, and then again when
Congress amended PURPA in 2005. These changes are not based on any
determination by the Commission that the encouragement directed by
PURPA is no longer needed. The question of whether QFs should continue
to be encouraged or not remains a question for Congress.
26. Moreover, PURPA also requires the Commission to insure that the
rates for QF purchases be ``just and reasonable to the electric
consumers of the electric utility and in the public interest[.]'' \35\
The obligation to encourage is also limited by the requirement that,
``No such rule prescribed under subsection (a) [the encouragement
provision] shall provide for a rate which exceeds the incremental cost
to the electric utility of alternative electric energy.'' \36\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\35\ 16 U.S.C. 824a-3(b).
\36\ 16 U.S.C. 824a-3(b).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
27. We recognize that some of the comments opposing the NOPR may
[[Page 54644]]
have been influenced by the Commission's recitation in the Background
section of the NOPR of the broad changes in circumstances since the
PURPA Regulations were first promulgated 40 years ago, including the
discovery of significant new natural gas reserves, the evolution of the
electric industry to include a significant independent power presence,
the establishment of organized competitive markets, and the advances in
renewable energy technologies.\37\ We clarify that the Commission
referenced this general background information in the NOPR primarily to
explain why it decided to re-evaluate its PURPA Regulations at all and
as Congress said we should, and not necessarily to support the
individual proposals included in the NOPR. The facts we rely on to
propose specific changes, which include some, but not all, of those
background facts, were cited in the specific sections of the NOPR
describing those proposed changes. And the facts on which we rely to
promulgate the specific changes in this final rule again are cited in
the specific sections describing those changes.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\37\ NOPR, 168 FERC ] 61,184, at PP 15-27.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
B. The Final Rule Ensures That the Commission's Implementation of PURPA
Continues To Benefit QFs, Purchasing Electric Utilities, and Electric
Consumers
28. The final rule implements additional changes consistent with
PURPA that also are designed to benefit QFs, purchasing utilities, and
electric consumers. The changes to the PURPA Regulations adopted in
this final rule will enable the Commission to continue satisfying the
statutory requirement that the Commission promulgate rules to encourage
QF development consistent with PURPA's requirements. Claims to the
contrary by commenters to the effect that the ``proposals are uniformly
biased against QF development'' \38\ have no merit.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\38\ Harvard Electricity Law Comments at 1.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
29. As an initial matter, we are not changing the determination in
the PURPA Regulations that QF rates must equal a purchasing electric
utility's full avoided costs.\39\ As the Supreme Court noted in API,
the full avoided cost rate requirement represents the maximum rate
permitted under PURPA, and thereby provides important encouragement to
QFs.\40\ The Court explained that the full avoided cost rate
requirement encourages QF development because QFs ``retain an incentive
to produce energy under the full-avoided-cost rule so long as their
marginal costs did not exceed the full avoided cost of the purchasing
utility.'' \41\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\39\ See 18 CFR 292.304(b)(2); NOPR, 168 FERC ] 61,184 at P 34.
\40\ API, 461 U.S. at 413. PURPA does not use the terms
``avoided cost'' or ``full avoided cost''; rather, PURPA uses the
term ``incremental cost of alternative electric energy.'' The
Commission's regulations and subsequent decisions have used the term
``avoided cost'' to explain the Commission's application of the
``incremental cost'' standard. The API decision and early Commission
precedents referred to ``full'' avoided costs to distinguish between
the Commission's decision to set QF rates at avoided costs and
proposals from certain parties that rates be set at something less
than avoided costs. We continue to use the terms avoided costs and
full avoided costs as being consistent with the statutory term
incremental cost.
\41\ Id. at 416.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
30. In addition, several of the changes to the current PURPA
Regulations implemented by this final rule are based expressly on a
finding that they are beneficial to QFs as well as to purchasing
utilities and ratepayers. For example, the provisions of the final rule
allowing for energy rates to be based on transparent, competitive
market prices--in appropriate circumstances--are supported by comments
submitted at the Technical Conference, where representatives of QFs and
utilities both expressed a preference for transparent prices for
QFs.\42\ This conclusion is supported by the Fitch Report, cited by
NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA, explaining how Fitch evaluates the
financial strength of renewable energy projects. In this report, Fitch
states that it gives a ``stronger'' evaluation to projects with power
sales contract prices that are ``indexed using simple, broad-based
publicly available indexation formulas.'' \43\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\42\ See American Forest & Paper Association, Comments, Docket
No. AD16-16-000, at 8 (filed June 8, 2016) (``To the extent
possible, these determinations [of avoided costs] should not be made
in a `black box', but rather, as part of an open and transparent
method and process.''); Edison Electric Institute (EEI) Comments,
Docket No. AD16-16-000, at 3 (filed June 30, 2016) (``Where
transparent competitive markets with day ahead prices exist, there
is no reason to adhere to second-best avoided cost pricing
mechanisms.'').
\43\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 37-38 (citing
FitchRatings, Global Infrastructure & Project Finance, Renewable
Energy Project Rating Criteria,'' at 3 (Feb. 26, 2019), https://www.fitchratings.com/site/re/10061770).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
31. Setting prices that are indexed using simple, broad-based
publicly available formulas is precisely what the Commission's changes
permitting reference to competitive market prices will achieve. Such
prices reflect avoided costs in a simpler, more transparent, and
predictable manner than through an administrative process, which should
encourage the development of QFs while at the same time providing
benefits to utilities and consumers. Using transparent market prices to
establish as-available avoided cost rates also allows QFs, utilities,
and the states to avoid the expenditure of the time and resources
involved in litigating administratively-set avoided cost rates, and
allows those rates to automatically adjust--up and down--as avoided
costs change.
32. Similarly, the provisions regarding competitive solicitations
adopted herein were added at the suggestion of both NARUC and certain
developers of renewable resource QFs, such as Solar Energy Industries.
These competitive solicitations can provide a fair and transparent
method for QFs to establish full avoided cost rates. As Solar Energy
Industries stated in its comments, ``[c]ompetitive solicitations, with
adequate safeguards, can deliver substantial value.'' \44\ Competitive
solicitations may be an especially appropriate tool in those regions
outside of Regional Transmission Organizations (RTOs) and Independent
System Operators (ISOs) where there are no organized competitive
markets where QFs can make sales.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\44\ Solar Energy Industries Comments at 38. Solar Energy
Industries agreed that the competitive solicitation provisions
proposed in the NOPR ``set forth many important safeguards,'' but
recommended that additional safeguards be implemented. Those
comments are discussed below, and we have specifically adopted Solar
Energy Industries request made earlier in this proceeding that all
competitive solicitations must be conducted pursuant to the
Commission's Allegheny standard. See Solar Energy Industries
Supplemental Comments, Docket No. AD16-16-000, at 32-34 (filed Aug.
28, 2019).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
33. Likewise, the LEO provisions adopted herein provide important
benefits to QFs. Under the current PURPA Regulations, a LEO gives QFs
the enforceable right to require utilities to purchase the QFs' power
at avoided cost rates.\45\ This is an important right that contributes
to a QF owner's ability to obtain financing, especially the development
financing needed to engage in the activities necessary to subsequently
obtain construction and permanent financing. However, the PURPA
Regulations are silent as to when and how a LEO is established, which
can leave QFs uncertain as to when this key right has been established.
By providing more specific guidance as to when a LEO is established,
the new rule creates greater certainty for QFs (and utilities) on this
important element of QF development.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\45\ See 18 CFR 292.304(d)(2). Although the final rule gives
states the flexibility to require that energy rates vary over the
term of the LEO and be calculated at the time of delivery, the final
rule retains the QF's option to choose a fixed capacity rate
calculated at the time the LEO is established.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
[[Page 54645]]
34. Some commenters assert that the guidance provided by the
Commission may make it more difficult to obtain a LEO.\46\ Their
specific concerns are discussed in detail below. But what those
commenters ignore is that, by establishing objective and reasonable
state-determined criteria limited to demonstrating commercial viability
and financial commitment, we also are protecting QFs against onerous
requirements for a LEO that hinder financing, such as a requirement for
a utility's execution of an interconnection agreement \47\ or power
purchase agreement,\48\ or requiring that QFs file a formal complaint
with the state commission,\49\ or limiting LEOs to only those QFs
capable of supplying firm power,\50\ or requiring the QF to be able to
deliver power in 90 days.\51\ By making clear in the PURPA Regulations
that such conditions are not permitted, but describing which
prerequisites a state may impose to establish a LEO to determine which
QFs are commercially viable and financially committed, we are providing
objective criteria to clarify when a LEO commences, which we find will
encourage the development of QFs.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\46\ See NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 81 (``[A]ny
requirement to demonstrate financing to create a LEO violates the
fundamental rule that the utility's actions should not be allowed to
deny the QF a LEO because the utility could prevent creation of a
LEO simply by refusing to sign the PPA needed to secure such
financing.''); Public Interest Organizations Comments at 98 (``[T]he
Commission's proposal to require QFs to demonstrate commercial
viability in order to obtain a LEO will prevent many QFs from ever
attaining commercial viability at all. Creating a new administrative
obstacle to QF financing in this way flies in the face of PURPA's
mandate to reduce barriers to QF development.''); Solar Energy
Industries Comments at 41 (``Establishing higher barriers to a
determination of `commercial viability' will only lead QF developers
to invest additional development capital and will simply weed out
those smaller companies that choose not to, or are unable to, invest
heavily in early-stage development activity before an avoided cost
rate is known. It is unjust and unreasonable to cause QFs to invest
tens of millions of dollars in site control, permit acquisition,
interconnection, and other development costs simply to secure the
opportunity to negotiate with the purchasing utility for a
contractual commitment.''); Southeast Public Interest Organizations
Comments at 41 (describing proposal as ``discourag[ing] QF
development since achieving some of the indicia suggested by the
Commission often circularly requires that QF developers have already
obtained financing'').
\47\ See, e.g., FLS Energy, Inc., 157 FERC ] 61,211, at P 26
(2016) (FLS) (stating that requiring signed interconnection
agreement as prerequisite to LEO is inconsistent with PURPA
Regulations).
\48\ See, e.g., Murphy Flat Power, LLC, 141 FERC ] 61,145, at P
24 (2012) (finding that requiring a signed and executed contract
with an electric utility as a prerequisite to a LEO is inconsistent
with PURPA Regulations.
\49\ See, e.g., Grouse Creek Wind Park, LLC, 142 FERC ] 61,187,
at P 40 (2013).
\50\ Exelon Wind 1, L.L.C. v. Nelson, 766 F.3d 380, 400 (5th
Cir. 2014).
\51\ Power Resource Group, Inc. v. Public Utility Comm'n of
Texas, 422 F.3d 231, (5th Cir. 2005).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
C. The Commission Is Not Eliminating Fixed Rate Pricing for QFs, But
Rather Is Giving States the Flexibility To Require the Same Variable
Energy Rate/Fixed Capacity Rate Construct That Applies Throughout the
Electric Industry
35. Another misconception reflected in several comments is that the
Commission proposed in the NOPR to eliminate fixed rate pricing for
QFs. Commenters argue that QFs cannot obtain financing without fixed
rates, and from this they claim that the proposal to give states the
flexibility to require variable energy rates would have a devastating
effect on future QF development.\52\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\52\ See, e.g., Public Interest Organizations Comments at 35-38
(allowing variable rates will further discourage wind and solar QF
development); Allco Comments at 9-11 (without the ability to obtain
a fixed long-term forecasted rate, QF solar energy development will
not exist).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
36. This assertion that the Commission has eliminated fixed rates
for QFs is not correct. The NOPR proposal (which we adopt in this final
rule) gave states the flexibility, should they choose to take advantage
of this flexibility, to require that the avoided cost energy rates in
QF contracts must vary depending on avoided costs at the time of
delivery (rather than being fixed at the time a LEO is incurred). The
NOPR thus made clear: ``Under the proposed revisions to Sec.
292.304(d), a QF would continue to be entitled to a contract with
avoided capacity costs calculated and fixed at the time the LEO is
incurred.'' \53\ We are retaining in this final rule the option granted
to QFs to fix their capacity rates for the term of their contracts at
the time the LEO is incurred.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\53\ See NOPR, 168 FERC ] 61,184 at P 66.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
37. The fact that we are giving states the flexibility to either
require QF contracts to have fixed capacity and variable energy rates
or to continue as before to provide QFs the option of fixed capacity
and fixed energy rates--has important consequences for the ability of
QF owners to finance their projects. The energy rates of purchasing
electric utilities, upon which avoided cost energy rates would be
based, typically reflect mainly the variable costs of producing energy,
such as the cost of fuel and variable operations and maintenance (O&M),
especially for a fossil fuel generator. Meanwhile, a purchasing
electric utility's capacity rates, upon which avoided cost capacity
rates would be based, tend to reflect fixed costs, including the
financing costs of facilities (i.e., debt repayment and a return on the
equity invested in the facility).\54\ Consequently, a fixed capacity
rate in a QF contract based on a purchasing electric utility's capacity
rates should typically be sufficient to recover the QF's financing
costs and should therefore continue to facilitate QF financing. We
recognize that a QF's financing costs may be different from the
purchasing electric utility's avoided costs and, therefore, the full
avoided cost rate that the QF receives may not support the financing of
a QF. But this is a consequence of how Congress structured PURPA, which
sets rates based on the avoided costs of the purchasing utility rather
than on the actual costs the QF incurs producing the power being
sold.\55\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\54\ See Order No. 69, FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 30,128 at 30,865.
\55\ See API, 461 U.S. at 414, 415 (stating that ``Congress did
not intend to impose traditional ratemaking concepts on sales by
qualifying facilities to utilities'' and that QFs ``would retain an
incentive to produce energy under the full-avoided-cost rule so long
as their marginal costs did not exceed the full avoided cost of the
purchasing utility'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
38. Another important aspect of the variable energy rate/fixed
capacity rate construct is that this is the standard rate structure
used throughout the electric industry for power sales agreements that
include the sale of capacity.\56\ That states will be allowed to
require QF contracts to be structured similarly to the contract
structure used in the rest of the electric industry has important
implications. In particular, this provides flexibility to states to
ensure that the avoided cost rate will be closer to the actual rate the
purchasing electric utility and its customers would have paid if the
purchasing electric utility had generated this electric energy itself
or purchased such electric energy from another source. Furthermore, the
record evidence demonstrating significant amounts of non-QF generation
facilities in operation today shows that the owners of such facilities
are able to obtain financing based on this same variable energy rate/
fixed capacity rate
[[Page 54646]]
construct.\57\ This represents important evidence that QFs likewise
should be able to obtain financing under the same rate construct,
especially considering that QFs benefit from the statutory right to
sell pursuant to a mandatory purchase obligation while non-QFs do not
have that right.\58\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\56\ Cf. Town of Norwood v. FERC, 962 F.2d 20, 21, 24 (D.C. Cir.
1992) (``The rate design before us, like most wholesale electric
rates, consists of separate monthly demand and energy charges. The
demand component is calculated to recover NEPCO's fixed (or
capacity-related) costs, such as construction and debt service,
which it incurs regardless of how much electricity it produces. The
energy charge is designed to recover the company's variable costs,
which it incurs only in the course of actually producing
electricity; fuel is a prime example. . . . With the cost outlook
constantly in flux due to changing economic conditions, some degree
of volatility is necessary if prices are to signal the market
accurately--as accurately, that is, as current prices can anticipate
future costs. Price volatility alone, therefore, cannot provide a
ground for overturning a marginal cost rate structure.'').
\57\ EIA, Form EIA-860 detailed data with previous form data
Early Release (EIA-860A/860B) (June 2, 2020), https://www.eia.gov/electricity/data/eia860/ shows 77.6 GW of operational QF nameplate
capacity and 450.453.5 GW of operational non-QF independent power
producer nameplate capacity as of end 2019.
\58\ Some commenters raise concerns with the Commission's
reliance on the financing of non-QF generation facilities to support
the conclusion that QFs could obtain financing with variable energy
rate contracts, pointing out that the Commission has not identified
any QFs that have obtained financing under this structure. The
reason for this, however, is that QFs typically do not employ this
structure because currently they are entitled to a fixed energy
rate/fixed capacity rate construct. Accordingly, evidence regarding
the financing of similar types of independently owned generation
projects by non-QFs using such a construct constitutes the best and
most relevant evidence of how it would affect QF financing.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
D. The Rate Changes Implemented by This Final Rule Put QF Rates on the
Same Footing as Electric Utility Rates and Are Not Discriminatory
39. The fact that variable energy rate/fixed capacity rate
contracts are standard in the electric industry also explains why,
contrary to assertions made by a number of commenters, allowing states
to require such contracts for QFs is not discriminatory.\59\ QFs
selling at wholesale pursuant to such contracts will be selling under
the same rate structure employed in the power sales contracts typically
used elsewhere in the electric industry, including by public utilities
when they make sales at wholesale to each other, and QFs will be doing
so at full avoided cost rates--the highest rates permitted under PURPA.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\59\ See, e.g., EPSA Comments at 9 (``The NOPR avoided rate
proposal must therefore be rejected because it puts QFs at a
disadvantage to utility-owned generation, in violation of the non-
discrimination mandate under PURPA.''); Public Interest
Organizations Comments at 51 (``[L]imiting QFs to contracts
providing no price certainty for energy values, while non-QF
generation regularly obtains fixed price contracts and utility-owned
generation receives guaranteed cost recovery from captive
ratepayers, constitutes discrimination.'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
40. It is true that electric utilities with franchised service
territories that make sales at retail are often effectively guaranteed
the recovery of their energy costs in their retail rates by their state
regulatory authorities--provided that such costs are prudently
incurred. But the electric utilities' retail rates are cost-based, such
that their rates are set based on costs they actually incur to produce
electricity for their customers. Importantly, moreover, the incremental
energy costs that an electric utility will recover from its retail
customers at an incremental level would be the same energy costs that
are used in determining the electric utilities' avoided costs that
will, in turn, set the as-available avoided cost rates to be charged by
QFs.
41. Thus, QF variable energy rate/fixed capacity rate contracts not
only would be structured similarly to the standard wholesale power
sales agreements used in the electric industry, but application of
traditional cost-based ratemaking principles to sales by QFs is exactly
what would be required in order to provide QFs with the same guaranteed
cost recovery that applies to electric utilities. Guaranteeing QFs cost
recovery is fundamentally inconsistent with PURPA, which sets the rate
the QF is paid at the purchasing electric utility's avoided cost, not
at the QF's cost. Such a rate structure is not discriminatory.
E. The PURPA Compliance Issues Raised by Some Commenters Are Outside
the Scope of This Rulemaking Proceeding
42. Finally, several commenters assert that certain states located
outside of RTO/ISO markets are dominated by large integrated public
utilities whose state commissions do not implement PURPA correctly.\60\
They argue that, as a consequence, there is little development of
independent generation--QFs or otherwise--in those states. They assert
that the proposals in the NOPR might be appropriate in states with RTO/
ISO markets that are subject to significant competition, but would only
make matters worse outside of the RTO/ISO markets.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\60\ American Dams Comments at 5-6; Biological Diversity
Comments at 13; CA Cogeneration Comments at 6-7; Con Edison Comments
at 2; ELCON Comments at 7-8; EPSA Comments at 1-2; IdaHydro Comments
at 5; NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 14-15; Solar Energy
Industries Comments at 15-20, 24; SC Solar Alliance Comments at 3-4;
Two Dot Wind Comments at 14-19.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
43. As explained above, several changes implemented by this final
rule ensure that the PURPA Regulations will continue to encourage QF
development. Other changes, such as allowing variable energy rates in
QF contracts, not only ensure the PURPA Regulations are consistent with
PURPA but also address some states' primary concern with the current
PURPA Regulations, i.e., the Commission's now allowing states the
flexibility to set variable energy rates could mitigate the states'
reluctance to implement PURPA in a way that better encourages
development of QFs. For example, the Idaho Commission has indicated
that its current policy of limiting QF contracts to two years is based
on its concern about fixed QF rates, and that the ability to require
variable energy rates could lead to longer contract terms.\61\ We
expect that these changes could facilitate QF development in states
where little QF capacity has been added to date.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\61\ See Idaho Commission Comments at 4 (stating that an energy
rate established at the time of contract formation that provides for
``revisions to the energy rate at regular intervals, consistent
with, for example, a purchasing electric utility's [integrated
resource plan] to reflect updated avoided cost calculations'' would
allow states to consider longer term contracts without putting
ratepayers at risk).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
44. Further, commenters' claims about lack of QF development
outside of the RTO/ISO markets appear to be overstated. For example,
the most recent data from the U.S. Energy Information Administration
(EIA) on the total amount of wind and solar QF capacity in each state
shows that 9 of the 20 states with the greatest combined wind and solar
QF capacity are located outside of the RTO/ISO markets.\62\ Of these 9
states, three are located in the Southeast--the region asserted by
commenters to be the most hostile to PURPA--including North Carolina,
which has the highest total amount of wind and solar QF capacity in the
country.\63\ Other states in the top 20 include Idaho--with the fourth
most wind and solar QF capacity--and Oregon,\64\ two states that have
been criticized as being hostile to PURPA. EIA data also shows that
five of the top 10 states in terms of renewable QF capacity additions
from 2008-17 are located outside of the RTO/ISO markets, including
North Carolina (with the most renewable QF capacity additions), Idaho,
Georgia, and Oregon,\65\ each of
[[Page 54647]]
which commenters have identified as being hostile to PURPA.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\62\ EIA, Form EIA-860 detailed data with previous form data
(EIA-860A/860B) Release date (June 2, 2020), https://www.eia.gov/electricity/data/eia860/. The top 20 states with combined QF solar
and wind nameplate capacity in 2018 were: (1) California, Texas,
Minnesota, Oklahoma, Massachusetts, New Mexico, Nebraska, New
Jersey, Michigan, New York, Illinois (all fully or partially inside
RTOs/ISOs); and (2) North Carolina, Idaho, Utah, South Carolina,
Georgia, Oregon, Colorado, Arizona, Wyoming(outside of RTOs/ISOs).
We note that some of these states are located in both RTO/ISO and
non-RTO/ISO regions.
\63\ Id. We note that five of the 20 states with the most solar
capacity--perhaps a better measure of the Southeast Region's PURPA
compliance given the lack of wind resources in this region--are
located in the Southeast.
\64\ Id.
\65\ See EIA, PURPA-qualifying capacity increases, but it's
still a small portion of added renewables (Aug. 16, 2018), https://www.eia.gov/todayinenergy/detail.php?id=36912.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
45. But whether any individual state has or has not failed to
implement the PURPA Regulations properly is not an issue for this final
rule, which implements changes to the PURPA Regulations but does not
modify Commission's rules for addressing claims that states are not
complying with the Commission's existing PURPA Regulations. We
promulgate this final rule based on the expectation that the states
will fulfill their legal obligation to implement the Commission's PURPA
Regulations as revised.\66\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\66\ 16 U.S.C. 824a-3(f)(1). The same obligation to implement
the Commission's PURPA Regulations as revised, we note, is imposed
on nonregulated electric utilities. 16 U.S.C. 824-3(f)(2).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
46. Further, although Congress required the Commission to establish
the general parameters for establishing QF rates, Congress delegated to
the states--not the Commission--the role to set QF rates.\67\ To the
extent that any entity believes a state is failing to implement the
Commission's PURPA Regulations, PURPA section 210(h) provides that
entity an avenue to seek relief.\68\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\67\ See 16 U.S.C. 824a-3(f)(1) (``[E]ach State regulatory
authority shall, after notice and opportunity for public hearing,
implement such rule (or revised rule) for each electric utility for
which it has ratemaking authority.'').
\68\ If the Commission, in response to a petition for
enforcement under PURPA section 210(h) against a state regulatory
authority, chooses not to initiate an enforcement action within 60
days of the filing of the petition, the statute authorizes the
petitioning electric utility or QF to itself initiate a suit
directly against the state in U.S. District Court. 16 U.S.C. 824a-
3(h)(2)(B). The same statutory provision similarly governs petitions
for enforcement against nonregulated electric utilities. Id. PURPA
section 210(g) also provides for review of state regulatory
authorities and nonregulated electric utilities in state fora. 16
U.S.C. 824a-3(g). The Commission's policies with respect to PURPA
enforcement are more fully set out in its Policy Statement Regarding
the Commission's Enforcement Role Under Section 210 of the Public
Utility Regulatory Policies Act of 1978, 23 FERC ] 61,304 (1983).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
III. Background
A. Passage of PURPA in 1978 and the Commission's Promulgation of Its
PURPA Regulations in 1980
47. PURPA was enacted in 1978 as part of a package of legislative
proposals intended to reduce the country's dependence on oil and
natural gas, which at the time were in short supply and subject to
dramatic price increases. PURPA sets forth a framework to encourage the
development of alternative generation resources that do not rely on
traditional fossil fuels (i.e., oil, natural gas and coal) and
cogeneration facilities that make more efficient use of the heat
produced from the fossil fuels that were then commonly used in the
production of electricity.
48. To accomplish this goal, PURPA section 210(a) directs that the
Commission ``prescribe, and from time to time thereafter revise, such
rules as [the Commission] determines necessary to encourage
cogeneration and small power production,'' \69\ including rules
requiring electric utilities to offer to sell electricity to, and
purchase electricity from, QFs. PURPA section 210(f) required each
state regulatory authority and nonregulated electric utility (together,
states) to implement the Commission's rules.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\69\ 16 U.S.C. 824a-3(a).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
49. In 1980, the Commission issued Order Nos. 69 and 70, which
promulgated the required rules that, with limited exceptions, remain in
effect today.\70\ The Commission explained that, at the time of the
passage of PURPA, cogenerators and small power producers faced three
major obstacles: (1) Electric utilities were not required to purchase
these generators' electric output or to make purchases at an
appropriate rate; (2) electric utilities sometimes charged
discriminatorily high rates for backup services; and (3) cogenerators
and small power producers ran the risk of being considered public
utilities themselves and thus being subject to state and federal
regulation as utilities.\71\ Further, at that time, there was no open
access transmission and little competition in electric wholesale
markets. Electric utilities were vertically-integrated and held
dominant market positions. As a result of their control over
transmission access, it was virtually impossible for third parties--
whether independent power producers or other electric utilities--to
compete with them to make sales of electricity.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\70\ Order No. 69, FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 30,128; Small Power
Production and Cogeneration Facilities--Qualifying Status, Order No.
70, FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 30,134 (cross-referenced at 10 FERC ]
61,230), orders on reh'g, Order No. 70-A, FERC Stats. & Regs. ]
30,159 (cross-referenced at 11 FERC ] 61,119) and FERC Stats. &
Regs. ] 30,160 (cross-referenced at 11 FERC ] 61,166), order on
reh'g, Order No. 70-B, FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 30,176 (cross-
referenced at 12 FERC ] 61,128), order on reh'g, FERC Stats. & Regs.
] 30,192 (1980) (cross-referenced at 12 FERC ] 61,306), amending
regulations, Order No. 70-D, FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 30,234 (cross-
referenced at 14 FERC ] 61,076), amending regulations, Order No. 70-
E, FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 30,274 (1981) (cross-referenced at 15 FERC
] 61,281).
\71\ Order No. 69, FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 30,128 at 30,863. See
infra P 78 & note 112 (addressing how the PURPA Regulations as
revised continue to address these obstacles).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
50. Given the Congressional mandate described above, the Commission
determined in Order No. 69 to set rates for sales by QFs equal to the
purchasing electric utilities' avoided costs.\72\ The Commission also
directed that electric utilities provide backup electric energy to QFs
on a non-discriminatory basis and at just and reasonable rates,\73\ and
that electric utilities interconnect with QFs.\74\ Pursuant to section
210(e) of PURPA,\75\ the Commission further provided exemptions from
many provisions of the FPA and state laws governing utility rates and
financial organization.\76\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\72\ 18 CFR 292.304(a)(2); see API, 461 U.S. at 412-18.
\73\ Order No. 69, FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 30,128 at 30,887-90;
see also 18 CFR 292.305.
\74\ Order No. 69, FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 30,128 at 30,874; see
also 18 CFR 292.303(c).
\75\ 16 U.S.C. 824a-3(e).
\76\ Order No. 69, FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 30,128 at 30,864;
accord id. at 30,863, 30,894-96; see also 18 CFR 292.601-.602.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
B. Circumstances Leading to the Commission's Re-Evaluation of the PURPA
Regulations and the Issuance of the NOPR
51. In the NOPR, the Commission described three important changes
in the circumstances that had originally prompted Congress to pass
PURPA in 1978. First, as the Commission explained, the United States
has seen an unprecedented change in the dynamics of the natural gas
market and the relevant supply and demand.\77\ Led by advancements in
production technologies, primarily in accessing shale reserves, natural
gas supplies increased dramatically.\78\ Further, the EIA forecasted
continued supply growth over the next 25 years.\79\ In short, as the
Commission found in issuing the NOPR, there no longer are shortages of
natural gas supply.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\77\ NOPR, 168 FERC ] 61,184 at P 19.
\78\ Domestic natural gas production, which appeared to peak in
the early 1970s at 21.7 Tcf per year, increased from 18.1 Tcf in
2005 to 30.4 Tcf in 2018. EIA, Monthly Energy Review (Aug. 27, 2019)
(in table 4.1 see column labeled ``Natural Gas Production (Dry)'' on
the Annual tab of the xls version), https://www.eia.gov/totalenergy/data/monthly/.
\79\ EIA's forecast showed supplies increasing to nearly 40 Tcf
by 2035 and 43 Tcf by 2050. EIA, Annual Energy Outlook 2018, at
tbl.13 (Jan. 24, 2019) (in table see row labeled ``Dry Gas
Production'' under the reference case) (Annual Energy Outlook 2019),
https://www.eia.gov/outlooks/aeo/data/browser/#/?id=13-AEO2019&cases=ref2018&sourcekey=0.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
52. Second, the Commission found that, since 1978, the outlook for
the development of alternatives to natural gas and oil-fired generation
resources, such as renewable resources, has changed equally
dramatically.\80\ The once-nascent renewables industry has grown and
matured over the past 40
[[Page 54648]]
years and has only accelerated subsequent to the Energy Policy Act of
2005's amendment of PURPA. The Commission noted that the cost of
building renewable facilities has decreased substantially to the point
that the cost of renewable resources is now or is shortly expected to
approach the cost of traditional electric generation.\81\ The
Commission also recognized that renewable resources (including hydro)
provide a significant share of the electricity currently generated in
the United States,\82\ that most renewable resources today are not
QFs,\83\ and that 65 percent of capacity additions in 2019 were
expected to come from renewable resources.\84\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\80\ NOPR, 168 FERC ] 61,184 at P 20.
\81\ Id. (citing EIA, Updated Capital Cost Estimates for Utility
Scale Electricity Generating Plants, https://www.eia.gov/analysis/studies/powerplants/capitalcost/; EIA, Levelized Cost and Levelized
Avoided Cost of New Generation Resources in the Annual Energy
Outlook 2019 (Feb. 2019), https://www.eia.gov/outlooks/aeo/pdf/electricity_generation.pdf; Lawrence Berkeley National Lab, Wind
Technologies Market Report, https://emp.lbl.gov/wind-technologies-market-report/). However, EIA has cautioned against directly
comparing the costs of dispatchable and nondispatchable generation:
Because load must be continuously balanced, generating units
with the capability to vary output to follow demand (dispatchable
technologies) generally have more value to a system than less
flexible units (nondispatchable technologies) such as those using
intermittent resources to operate. The LCOE values for dispatchable
and non-dispatchable technologies are listed separately in the
tables because comparing them must be done carefully.
EIA, Levelized Cost and Levelized Avoided Cost of New Generation
Resources in the Annual Energy Outlook 2019, at 2 (Feb. 2019),
https://www.eia.gov/outlooks/archive/aeo19/pdf/electricity_generation.pdf.
\82\ NOPR, 168 FERC ] 61,184 at P 21 (citing EIA, August 2019
Monthly Energy Review at Figure 7.2a, https://www.eia.gov/totalenergy/data/monthly; Office of Energy Projects, Energy
Infrastructure Update For July 2019 at 4 (July 2019), https://www.ferc.gov/legal/staff-reports/2019/july-energy-infrastructure.pdf).
\83\ NOPR, 168 FERC ] 61,184 at P 22.
\84\ Id. (citing EIA, Today in Energy, New electric generating
capacity in 2019 will come from renewables and natural gas (Jan. 10,
2019), https://www.eia.gov/todayinenergy/detail.php?id=37952 (Form
EIA-860M, Preliminary Monthly Electric Generator Inventory).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
53. Third, the introduction of QFs as competing sources of
electricity to the incumbent electric utilities has led to the
development of significant non-QF independent power production.\85\ In
addition, RTOs and ISOs have developed competitive wholesale electric
markets that serve roughly two-thirds of electricity consumers in the
United States.\86\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\85\ NOPR, 168 FERC ] 61,184 at P 25. The Commission cited to
data showing that that net generation of energy by non-utility owned
renewable resources in the United States escalated from 51.7 TWh in
2005 when EPAct 2005 was passed, to 340 TWh in 2018. This also
included significant growth in non-utility renewable resources in
states outside of RTOs. For example, net generation by non-utility
renewable resources in the region defined by EIA as the Mountain
State region increased from 3.6 TWh in 2005 to 19.5 TWh in 2012, and
to 42.5 TWh in 2018. Pacific Northwest (Oregon and Washington) net
non-utility generation from renewable resources increased from 1.5
TWh in 2005, to 8.7 TWh in 2012, and to 10.6 TWh in 2018. In the
Southeast region of the country, non-utility renewable resources saw
a lesser increase from 2.6 TWh in 2005 to 2.7 TWh in 2012, but
expanded to 6.5 TWh in 2018. NOPR, 168 FERC ] 61,184 at P 27 (citing
data taken from EIA's Electricity Data Browser, www.eia.gov/electricity/data/browser (select net generation, other renewables,
independent power producers)).
\86\ ISO/RTO Council, The Role of ISOs and RTOs, https://isorto.org.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
54. In PURPA section 210(a), Congress directed not only that the
Commission prescribe regulations, but that the Commission revise those
regulations ``from time to time thereafter.'' \87\ The Commission
determined in the NOPR that, in light of these dramatic changes in
circumstances since the passage of PURPA, it was appropriate to review
the PURPA Regulations to determine whether changes to those regulations
were warranted consistent with our statutory mandate.\88\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\87\ 16 U.S.C. 824a-3(a).
\88\ 16 U.S.C. 824a-3(b).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
55. After identifying these three important changes in the industry
that have taken place since 1980, we further identified evidence
demonstrating that overestimations of avoided cost have not been
balanced by underestimations, and that this trend may persist with the
general decline in the cost of electricity.\89\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\89\ See NOPR, 168 FERC ] 61,184 at P 30. Evidence submitted in
response to the NOPR shows that, as a result, customers may be
paying more than avoided costs. See infra PP 265 (``Duke Energy
claims that, among the factors contributing to this overpayment of
$2.26 billion for the remainder of these QF contracts, the primary
factor has been the requirement to offer fixed avoided cost energy
rates during a period of rapidly declining energy prices''), 268
(``Massachusetts DPU argues that a 10-year, fixed energy rate based
on current New England wholesale energy market prices is highly
likely to diverge from actual energy market prices over the ten-year
contract term and could significantly harm ratepayers'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
C. Summary of Changes to the PURPA Regulations Implemented by This
Final Rule
56. We now are revising our PURPA Regulations based on the record
of this proceeding, including comments submitted in the technical
conference in Docket No. AD16-16-000 (Technical Conference),\90\ the
record evidence cited in the NOPR, and the comments submitted in
response to the NOPR. These changes, including modifications to the
proposals made in the NOPR, are summarized below.\91\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\90\ Supplemental Notice of Technical Conference, Implementation
Issues Under the Public Utility Regulatory Policies Act of 1978,
Docket No. AD16-16-000 (May 9, 2016). The Technical Conference
covered such issues as: (1) Various methods for calculating avoided
cost; (2) the obligation to purchase pursuant to a LEO; (3)
application of the one-mile rule; and (4) the rebuttable presumption
the Commission has adopted under PURPA section 210(m) that QFs 20 MW
and below do not have nondiscriminatory access to competitive
organized wholesale markets.
\91\ In its post-NOPR comments, Bloom Energy requested that the
Commission ``[u]pdate the definition of `useful thermal energy
output' of a topping-cycle cogeneration facility to reflect the
commercialization of solid oxide fuel cells that produce heat for
the industrial purpose of producing hydrogen, a fuel that the fuel
cells use to generate electricity.'' Bloom Energy Comments at 2. We
do not take action on this request in this proceeding because we do
not view this proposal as a logical outgrowth of the NOPR.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
57. First, we grant states the flexibility to require that energy
rates (but not capacity rates) in QF power sales contracts and other
LEOs \92\ vary in accordance with changes in the purchasing electric
utility's as-available avoided costs at the time the energy is
delivered. Under this change, if a state exercises this flexibility, a
QF no longer would have the ability to elect to have its energy rate be
fixed, but would continue to be entitled to a fixed capacity rate for
the term of the contract or LEO.\93\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\92\ The Commission has held that a LEO can take effect before a
contract is executed and may not necessarily be incorporated into a
contract. JD Wind 1, LLC, 129 FERC ] 61,148, at P 25 (2009), reh'g
denied, 130 FERC ] 61,127 (2010) (``[A] QF, by committing itself to
sell to an electric utility, also commits the electric utility to
buy from the QF; these commitments result either in contracts or in
non-contractual, but binding, legally enforceable obligations.'').
For ease of reference, however, references herein to a contract also
are intended to refer to a LEO that is not incorporated into a
contract.
\93\ Moreover, any state--whether located in regions where
energy prices are competitively based or whether located in regions
where they are not--would be permitted to require that the fixed
energy rate established at the time of the contract include
provisions, established at the time the contract is established,
providing for revisions to the energy rate at regular intervals,
consistent with, for example, a purchasing electric utility's
integrated resource plan, to reflect updated avoided cost
calculations.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
58. Second, we grant states additional flexibility to allow QFs to
have a fixed energy rate, but to provide that such state-authorized
fixed energy rate can be based on projected energy prices during the
term of a QF's contract based on the anticipated dates of delivery.
59. Third, we grant states flexibility to set ``as-available'' QF
energy rates as follows: We are establishing a rebuttal presumption,
rather than a per se rule as proposed in the NOPR, that the LMP
established in the organized electric markets defined in 18 CFR
292.309(e), (f), or (g) represents the as-available avoided costs of
electric utilities located in these markets.\94\ So long as this
[[Page 54649]]
presumption is not rebutted, a state can at its option establish as-
available energy avoided cost rates for QFs selling to such electric
utilities at the LMP. With respect to QFs selling to electric utilities
located outside of the organized electric markets defined in 18 CFR
292.309(e), (f), or (g), states have the option to set as-available
energy avoided cost rates at competitive prices from liquid market hubs
or calculated from a formula based on natural gas price indices and
specified heat rates, provided that the states first determine that
such prices represent the purchasing electric utilities' avoided costs.
The states would have the flexibility to choose to adopt one or more of
these options or to continue setting QF rates under the standards long
established in the PURPA Regulations.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\94\ These are the markets operated by Midcontinent Independent
System Operator, Inc. (MISO); PJM Interconnection, L.L.C. (PJM); ISO
New England Inc. (ISO-NE); New York Independent System Operator,
Inc. (NYISO); Electric Reliability Council of Texas (ERCOT);
California Independent System Operator, Inc. (CAISO); and Southwest
Power Pool, Inc. (SPP).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
60. Fourth, states would have the flexibility to set energy and
capacity rates pursuant to a competitive solicitation process conducted
pursuant to transparent and non-discriminatory procedures consistent
with the Commission's Allegheny standard, described in this final rule.
61. Fifth, we do not adopt the proposed rule permitting states with
retail competition to allow relief from the purchase obligation. We
instead clarify in this final rule that the Commission's existing PURPA
Regulations already require that states, to the extent practicable,
must account for reduced loads in setting QF capacity rates.
62. Sixth, we modify the Commission's ``one-mile rule'' for
determining whether generation facilities are considered to be at the
same site for purposes of determining qualification as a qualifying
small power production facility. Specifically, we allow electric
utilities, state regulatory authorities, and other interested parties
to show that affiliated small power production facilities that use the
same energy resource and are more than one mile apart and less than 10
miles apart actually are at the same site (with distances one mile or
less apart still irrebuttably at the same site, and distances 10 miles
or more apart irrebuttably at separate sites). We also allow a small
power production facility seeking QF status to provide further
information in its certification (whether a self-certification or an
application for Commission certification) or recertification (whether a
self-recertification or an application for Commission recertification)
to defend preemptively against subsequent challenges, by identifying
factors affirmatively demonstrating that its facility is indeed at a
separate site from other affiliated small power production qualifying
facilities. We further add a definition of the term ``electrical
generating equipment'' to the PURPA Regulations to clarify how the
distance between facilities is to be calculated.
63. Seventh, we allow an entity to challenge an initial self-
certification or self-recertification without being required to file a
separate petition for declaratory order and to pay the associated
filing fee. However, we clarify in this final rule that such protests
may be made to new certifications (both self-certifications and
applications for Commission certification) but to only self-
recertifications and applications for Commission recertifications
making substantive changes to the existing certification.
64. Eighth, we revise the Commission's regulations implementing
PURPA section 210(m), which provide for the termination of an electric
utility's obligation to purchase from a QF with nondiscriminatory
access to certain markets. Currently, there is a rebuttable presumption
that QFs with a net capacity at or below 20 MW do not have
nondiscriminatory access to such markets. We update the rebuttable
presumption for small power production facilities (but not cogeneration
facilities) from 20 MW to 5 MW and, in this final rule, revise the
regulations to include examples of factors, among others, that QFs may
argue show that they lack nondiscriminatory access to such markets.
65. Finally, we clarify that a QF must demonstrate commercial
viability and a financial commitment to construct its facility pursuant
to objective and reasonable state-determined criteria before the QF is
entitled to a contract or LEO. States may not impose any requirements
for a LEO other than a showing of commercial viability and a financial
commitment to construct the facility. We also clarify in this final
rule that, to the extent that the permitting factor is relied upon, a
QF need only show that it has applied for all required permits and paid
all applicable fees, and not that it has obtained such permits.
66. As explained in detail in the relevant sections below, these
changes will enable the Commission to continue to fulfill its statutory
obligations under sections 201 and 210 of PURPA. We emphasize that
these changes are effective prospectively for new contracts or LEOs and
for new facility certifications and recertifications filed on or after
the effective date of this final rule; we do not by this final rule
permit disturbance of existing contracts or LEOs or existing facility
certifications.
IV. Discussion
A. General Legal Standards Under PURPA
67. Several comments were submitted regarding: (1) The requirement
in PURPA section 210(a) that ``the Commission shall prescribe, and from
time to time thereafter revise, such rules as it determines necessary
to encourage cogeneration and small power production''; and (2) the
requirement in PURPA section 210(b) that rates paid by purchasing
utilities to QFs ``shall not discriminate against qualifying
cogenerators or qualifying small power producers.'' \95\ In addition, a
claim was made that the Commission has unlawfully delegated its
authority to the states. These comments apply to several of the
revisions implemented by this final rule and therefore are discussed
prior to the discussion of specific revisions implemented herein.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\95\ 16 U.S.C. 824a-3(a), (b).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
1. Encouragement of QFs
a. Comments
68. Commenters make two general arguments regarding the statutory
requirement that the Commission's PURPA Regulations should encourage
QFs. First, they note that the statutory requirement that the PURPA
Regulations encourage QFs is mandatory and that the Commission has no
discretion to determine that such encouragement no longer is necessary.
Harvard Electricity Law states that ``Congress'[s] mandate to encourage
QFs is not contingent on industry conditions and does not expire.''
\96\ Further, they assert, ``[t]he Commission may not overwrite
Congress's instruction to issue rules that it `determines necessary to
encourage cogeneration and small power production.' '' \97\ Public
Interest Organizations similarly object to the NOPR as violating the
encouragement requirement because, they assert, the NOPR ``reflect[s] a
belief that the current rules support too much QF development and a
desire to reduce the incentives in current rules for QF development.''
\98\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA assert that ``[t]he Commission cannot
take it
[[Page 54650]]
upon itself to change the underlying policy directives to encourage
QFs.'' \99\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\96\ Harvard Electricity Law Comments at 1.
\97\ Id. at 4 (quoting PURPA section 210(a)).
\98\ Public Interest Organizations Comments at 10.
\99\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 29.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
69. Public Interest Organizations advance a second general argument
based on the encouragement requirement, arguing that ``[t]o amend the
rules, the Commission must first determine that the actual changes it
proposes increase development and utilization of QFs.'' \100\
Similarly, Allco attacks the NOPR on the grounds that ``the proposed
changes do not encourage QF generation.'' \101\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\100\ Public Interest Organizations Comments at 11.
\101\ Allco Comments at 8.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
b. Commission Determination
70. We agree with commenters that PURPA does not provide discretion
to the Commission to determine whether QFs should be encouraged. That
is a determination left to Congress, and we have not premised this
final rule on a belief that QFs should not be encouraged. However, the
requirement that the Commission promulgate regulations necessary to
encourage QFs is not unbounded. Instead, as noted briefly earlier,
there are statutory limitations on the extent that the PURPA
Regulations can encourage QFs.
71. First, PURPA section 210(b) sets out standards with which the
Commission must comply in setting QF rates. The last sentence of PURPA
section 210(b) sets out an upper limit on such rates. ``No such rule
prescribed under subsection (a) shall provide for a rate which exceeds
the incremental cost to the electric utility of alternative electric
energy.'' \102\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\102\ Furthermore, PURPA section 210(b)(1) requires that QF
rates be ``just and reasonable to the electric consumers of the
electric utility and in the public interest.'' 16 U.S.C. 824a-
3(b)(1). Although the exact scope of the ``just and reasonable to
the electric consumers'' criterion has never been addressed
explicitly, the Supreme Court held in API that the requirement in
the PURPA Regulations that QF rates be set at full avoided costs
does not violate this criterion. API, 461 U.S. at 415-16. This
``just and reasonable to the electric consumers'' criterion likely
would be violated if the Commission were to allow a rate above the
purchasing electric utility's avoided costs.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
72. If there were any doubt from the statutory language that
incremental costs (avoided costs) are intended to be a hard cap on QF
rates, such doubt is dispelled by the Conference Report to PURPA, which
provided: ``This limitation on the rates which may be required in
purchasing from a cogenerator or small power producer is meant to act
as an upper limit on the price at which utilities can be required under
this section to purchase electric energy.'' \103\ The Conference Report
also described the reason for the avoided cost cap on QF rates. ``The
provisions of this section are not intended to require the rate payers
of a utility to subsidize cogenerators or small power produc[er]s.''
\104\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\103\ Conf. Rep. at 98 (emphasis added).
\104\ Id. (emphasis added).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
73. Therefore, PURPA section 210(b) imposes an important limit on
the Commission's ability to encourage QFs by imposing an upper boundary
on the rates at which QFs may require electric utilities to purchase
their electric energy. The Commission cannot require QF rates that
exceed the avoided costs of the purchasing electric utility.\105\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\105\ 16 U.S.C. 824a-3(b)(1).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
74. Second, another way in which Congress limited the Commission's
ability to encourage QFs was to define small power production
facilities, the PURPA category applicable to almost all renewable
resources that wish to be QFs, as having ``a power production capacity
which, together with any other facilities located at the same site (as
determined by the Commission), is not greater than 80 megawatts.''
\106\ The statutory 80 MW limitation, as well as any definition of
``the same site'' that may be established by the Commission, will of
necessity have an effect on the encouragement of QFs, because it will
limit the capacity of QFs both ab initio and also for those located at
the same site to 80 MW.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\106\ 16 U.S.C. 796(17)(A)(ii).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
75. Third, Congress amended PURPA section 210 to add section
210(m), which provides for termination of the requirement that an
electric utility enter into a new obligation or contract to purchase
from a QF if the QF has nondiscriminatory access to certain defined
types of markets.\107\ We interpret this amendment as reflecting
Congress's judgment that these markets provide adequate encouragement
for those QFs having nondiscriminatory access to such markets. To the
extent that a party asserts that the termination of the purchase
obligation for QFs with nondiscriminatory access to these markets
discourages QFs, that party's argument is not with the Commission, but
rather with Congress. PURPA section 210(m) obligates the Commission to
grant any request to terminate a utility's obligation to purchase from
a QF with nondiscriminatory access to the specified markets.\108\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\107\ See 16 U.S.C. 824a-3(m).
\108\ Id. (``[N]o electric utility shall be required to enter
into a new contract or obligation to purchase electric energy from a
[QF] if the Commission finds that the [QF] has nondiscriminatory
access to [specified markets].'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
76. Finally, we disagree with any suggestion that a rule originally
adopted in 1980 cannot be changed once adopted, or that our revised
regulations cannot be different in how they encourage QFs than the
regulations the Commission issued in 1980.\109\ For one thing, as
explained above, PURPA itself includes certain limitations on the
Commission's ability to encourage QFs, and a provision in the final
rule intended to comply with these statutory limitations cannot be
found to violate PURPA even if such a provision individually does not
affirmatively encourage QFs to the same degree now as in 1980. As
explained herein, we do not seek, through this final rule, to cease
encouraging the development of QFs. Instead, this final rule is
intended to ensure that the Commission is compliant with the statute in
how it does encourage the development of QFs. In doing so, the
Commission may end up encouraging QF development differently from the
current PURPA Regulations, but the Commission's regulations continue to
encourage QF development, as contemplated by PURPA.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\109\ See 18 U.S.C. 824a-3(a).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
77. Many of the commenters' assertions seem to be based on a
reading of the statute that requires that every individual change made
to the PURPA Regulations in isolation must individually encourage QFs
notwithstanding the statute's provisions. But, as discussed above,
Congress established boundaries in PURPA that must be considered, such
as the ``cap'' on incremental costs; just and reasonable rates for
electric customers; the 80 MW limit; and whether QFs have
nondiscriminatory access to markets. Furthermore, the statutory
requirement to encourage QF development applies to the PURPA
Regulations--``such rules as [the Commission] determines necessary''--
as a whole.\110\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\110\ See 16 U.S.C. 824a-3(a) (emphasis added).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
78. In that regard, we find that the Commission's PURPA Regulations
as a whole when modified by this final rule continue to encourage the
development of QFs, consistent with PURPA. The PURPA Regulations in
particular, continue to require that QF rates be set at full avoided
costs, a provision the Supreme Court described as ``provid[ing] the
maximum incentive for the development of cogeneration and small power
production.'' \111\ In addition, this final rule retains provisions of
the PURPA Regulations adopted in 1980 that provide encouragement
through other means
[[Page 54651]]
recognized by the Supreme Court in FERC v. Miss.\112\ (e.g., certain
regulatory relief,\113\ interconnection provisions,\114\ and
requirements that utilities sell power to QFs that will enable QFs to
continue operations).\115\ Moreover, several of the changes implemented
by this final rule also provide additional encouragement for QFs as
described in more detail below.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\111\ API, 461 U.S. at 418.
\112\ 456 U.S. 742, 750-51 (1982) (holding that Congress ``felt
that two problems impeded the development of nontraditional
generating facilities: (1) Traditional electricity utilities were
reluctant to purchase power from, and to sell power to, the
nontraditional facilities, and (2) the regulation of these
alternative energy sources by state and federal utility authorities
imposed financial burdens upon the nontraditional facilities and
thus discouraged their development'' (internal citations omitted)).
\113\ 18 CFR 292.601-02.
\114\ 18 CFR 292.303(c).
\115\ 18 CFR 292.305.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
2. Discrimination
a. Comments
79. Commenters opposing the proposals in the NOPR also cite to the
statutory requirement in PURPA section 210(b)(1) that QF rates ``shall
not discriminate against'' QFs. EPSA asserts that ``[n]otably, this
standard is more restrictive than the [FPA's] prohibition against
`unduly discriminatory' rates.'' \116\ Public Interest Organizations
state that ``[i]n other statutes, prohibiting price discrimination
without the modifiers `unreasonable' or `undue,' means any difference
in price for the same commodity.'' \117\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\116\ EPSA Comments at 8.
\117\ Public Interest Organizations Comments at 47 (citing FTC
v. Anheuser-Busch, Inc., 363 U.S. 536, 549 (1960)).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
80. In discussing the requirement that QF rates not be
discriminatory, some commenters compare the treatment afforded to QFs
under the NOPR with the rate treatment applicable to public utilities.
For example, NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA point out that ``[u]tilities
can rate-base long-term investments, thereby ensuring that they can
recover their capital investments plus an authorized return, and then
also recover their actual operating costs under traditional cost-of-
service ratemaking.'' \118\ By contrast, Harvard Electricity Law
asserts, ``QFs do not have the same ability that the electric utilities
have to `rate base' their facilities and, thereby, guarantee capital
recovery.'' \119\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\118\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 36; see also
IdaHydro Comments at 11; Industrial Energy Consumers Comments at 12-
13; SC Solar Alliance Comments at 5-10; Solar Energy Industries
Comments at 33, 36-38.
\119\ Harvard Electricity Law Comments at 28.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
81. Based on this difference between utilities and QFs, commenters
allege that certain aspects of the NOPR are discriminatory, including
those provisions of the NOPR regarding the use of LMPs and other
competitive rates to set as-available energy rates,\120\ to allow for
variable energy rates in QF contracts,\121\ and to allow avoided costs
to be set through competitive solicitations (i.e., requests for
proposals (RFPs)).\122\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\120\ See, e.g., Public Interest Organizations Comments at 64
(stating that the use of competitive prices to set as-available
energy avoided cost rates is discriminatory because non-QF
generators are not limited to competitive prices and utilities can,
and regularly do, pay effective prices for energy that exceed the
price determined by competitive prices).
\121\ See, e.g., EPSA Comments at 9 (``The NOPR avoided rate
proposal must therefore be rejected because it puts QFs at a
disadvantage to utility-owned generation, in violation of the non-
discrimination mandate under PURPA.''); Public Interest
Organizations Comments at 51 (``[L]imiting QFs to contracts
providing no price certainty for energy values, while non-QF
generation regularly obtains fixed price contracts and utility-owned
generation receives guaranteed cost recovery from captive
ratepayers, constitutes discrimination.'').
\122\ See, e.g., Allco Comments at 12 (stating that allowing a
state commission to use a competitive solicitation price is simply
giving another tool to a state commission to kill QF projects).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
b. Commission Determination
82. As an initial matter, we agree with EPSA that the statutory
requirement in PURPA section 210(b)(1) that QF rates ``shall not
discriminate against'' QFs is more restrictive than the FPA's
prohibition against 'unduly discriminatory' rates.\123\ However, the
avoided cost cap on QF rates that limits the Commission's ability to
encourage QFs, discussed above, also applies to the Commission's
ability to address these claims of discrimination under PURPA. PURPA
section 210(b) makes clear that ``[n]o such rule prescribed under
subsection (a) shall provide for a rate which exceeds the incremental
cost to the electric utility of alternative electric energy.'' \124\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\123\ EPSA Comments at 8.
\124\ Furthermore, as noted above, PURPA section 210(b)(1)
requires that QF rates also be ``just and reasonable to the electric
consumers of the electric utility and in the public interest.'' See
supra note 102.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
83. We are retaining in this final rule the requirement that QF
rates be set at a purchasing utility's full avoided costs. The Supreme
Court held in API that ``the full-avoided-cost rule plainly satisfies
the nondiscrimination requirement.'' \125\ Although the Court did not
provide a detailed explanation for this holding, the reasoning is
apparent. If the purchasing utility is paying the same rate to a QF for
power that it otherwise would have paid for incremental power, by
definition such a rate could not be discriminatory. But even if it were
possible to posit a situation where the payment of a full avoided cost
rate to a QF somehow were discriminatory, the Commission nevertheless
would be prohibited by PURPA section 210(b) from requiring a rate to be
paid to the QF that is above the full avoided costs of the purchasing
electric utility.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\125\ API, 461 U.S. at 413.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
84. For the same reasons, Public Interest Organizations are
mistaken when they assert that, without the modifiers ``unreasonable''
or ``undue,'' any difference in price for the same commodity violates
PURPA.\126\ So long as a QF's rate is set at the purchasing utility's
full avoided cost, the QF's rate should be the same as the rate the
purchasing utility otherwise would be paying or the cost it would be
incurring, and such a rate would not be discriminatory. And, in any
event, as noted above, the Commission cannot require a rate that is any
higher.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\126\ Public Interest Organizations Comments at 47 (citing FTC
v. Anheuser-Busch, Inc., 363 U.S. at 549).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
85. With respect to comparisons between QFs, with no guarantee of
cost recovery, and electric utilities, which if they have a franchised
service territory and sell at retail in that territory are effectively
guaranteed the opportunity to seek to recover prudently-incurred costs
in their retail rates, we observe that Congress acknowledged this
difference when enacting PURPA. As emphasized in the PURPA Conference
Report:
The conferees recognize that cogenerators and small power
producers are different from electric utilities, not being
guaranteed a rate of return on their activities generally or on the
activities vis a vis the sale of power to the utility and whose risk
in proceeding forward in the cogeneration or small power production
enterprise is not guaranteed to be recoverable.\127\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\127\ Conf. Rep. at 97-98 (emphasis added).
86. In recognizing this difference and yet not seeking to eliminate
it, Congress also made clear its intent not to treat QFs like electric
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
utilities in this regard:
It is not the intention of the conferees that [QFs] become
subject . . . to the type of examination that is traditionally given
to electric utility rate applications to determine what is the just
and reasonable rate that they should receive for their electric
power.\128\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\128\ Id. at 97.
87. Based on this legislative history, the Supreme Court concluded
in API that, ``Congress did not intend to impose traditional ratemaking
concepts on sales by qualifying facilities to utilities.'' \129\ But
application of traditional cost-based ratemaking principles to sales by
QFs is
[[Page 54652]]
exactly what would be required in order to provide QFs with the same
guaranteed cost recovery that applies to electric utilities. Also,
guaranteeing QFs cost recovery is fundamentally inconsistent with
PURPA, which sets the rate the QF is paid at the utility's avoided
cost, not at the QF's cost.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\129\ API, 461 U.S. at 414.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
88. It therefore is clear that Congress did not intend for the
PURPA nondiscrimination criterion to require that QF rates be set in a
way that guarantees recovery of a QF's own costs, even as Congress
recognized that franchised electric utilities selling at retail
typically do have such guarantees for their own costs. Congress thus
withheld from the Commission the authority to provide to QFs the same
opportunity to recover costs at retail that franchised electric
utilities have to recover their costs at retail; it was done by
Congress intentionally and cannot be impermissibly discriminatory.\130\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\130\ See 16 U.S.C. 824a-3(a) (rules Commission is directed to
prescribe ``may not authorize a [QF] to make any sale for purposes
other than resale'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
3. Unlawful Delegation and the Role of Nonregulated Electric Utilities
a. Comments
89. Allco argues that PURPA section 210(f) requires states to
``implement'' the Commission's rules, and that those rules cannot
redelegate the Commission's authority. Allco claims that the statutory
requirement to implement the Commission's rules cannot simply be a
fa[ccedil]ade for delegating broad authority to states to undercut
PURPA's directive that QF small power production must be encouraged.
Allco concludes that Congress intended for the Commission to adopt
actual rules rather than ``a menu of factors'' that essentially leaves
states with all the discretion as to what to implement in order to
encourage QF generation.\131\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\131\ Allco Comments at 39-40.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
90. Allco also asserts that the NOPR's proposed delegation of
authority to nonregulated electric utilities is an unconstitutional
delegation. According to Allco, such a delegation would mean that
nonregulated electric utilities (some of which are among the largest
utilities in the United States) were regulating themselves. Allco
argues that a private entity such as a nonregulated electric utility
cannot constitutionally be delegated regulatory power.\132\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\132\ Id. at 40 (citing Ass'n of Am. R.R. v. DOT, 721 F.3d 666,
677 (D.C. Cir. 2013), vacated on other grounds, 135 S. Ct. 1225
(2015)).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
91. Nebraska Board states that there is no state agency in Nebraska
that has ratemaking authority over retail electric suppliers and that
all retail electric suppliers are consumer-owned. Nebraska Board states
its understanding that each retail electric supplier in Nebraska would
have jurisdiction to exercise flexibilities provided to states in the
NOPR.
92. Public Interest Organizations argue that the Commission failed
to comply with PURPA section 210's requirement to consult with federal
and state regulatory agencies with ratemaking authority.\133\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\133\ Public Interest Organizations Comments at 19 (citing 16
U.S.C. 824a-3(a)).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
b. Commission Determination
93. Allco's unlawful delegation claims are misplaced. By enacting
PURPA section 210(f)(1), Congress delegated to the states the
obligation to implement the Commission's PURPA rules, and the
Commission is acting consistent with that delegation. Congress's
delegation to the states was upheld in FERC v. Miss.\134\ and we are
ensuring that the rules we have imposed abide by all the terms of the
statute. Further, the Commission's current PURPA Regulations,
promulgated in 1980, set forth a list of factors that the states are to
consider, ``to the extent practicable,'' in setting QF rates.\135\ In
so doing, the Commission emphasized that states have ``great latitude
in determining the manner of implementation of the Commission's rules,
provided that the manner chosen is reasonably designed to implement the
requirements of Subpart C [which includes the pricing rules of 18 CFR
292.304].'' \136\ This final rule adds factors that must be taken into
account to the extent practicable in setting rates, while retaining the
``great latitude'' the states always have had to implement the PURPA
Regulations and which have been an important feature of the
Commission's PURPA Regulations since their inception.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\134\ 456 U.S. at 760 (``FERC has declared that state
commissions may implement this by, among other things, `an
undertaking to resolve disputes between qualifying facilities and
electric utilities arising under [PURPA].' '').
\135\ 18 CFR 292.304(e).
\136\ Order No. 69, FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 30,128 at 30,891-92.
The Commission explained that ``[s]uch latitude is necessary in
order for implementation to accommodate local conditions and
concerns, so long as the final plan is consistent with statutory
requirements.'' Policy Statement Regarding the Commission's
Enforcement Role Under Section 210 of the Public Utility Regulatory
Policies Act of 1978, 23 FERC ] 61,304,at 61,646.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
94. With respect to Allco's claim that the NOPR proposed an
unconstitutional delegation to nonregulated electric utilities, we note
that PURPA section 210(f)(2) specifically provides that ``each
nonregulated electric utility shall, after notice and opportunity for
public hearing, implement'' the Commission's rules regarding the rates
to be paid to QFs. Consistent with this statutory provision, the PURPA
Regulations regarding the setting of QF rates have applied to
nonregulated electric utilities since those regulations were
promulgated in 1980.\137\ The final rule does nothing more than
continue to implement this statutory requirement in the same way it
always has been implemented. Given PURPA's unique statutory scheme
involving state regulatory authorities, nonregulated electric
utilities, QFs, and the Commission, we therefore reject Allco's
assertion that the rules proposed in the NOPR--and adopted in this
final rule--establish an unconstitutional delegation of authority to a
private entity.\138\ And it is beyond the Commission's purview to
consider whether this statutory grant is constitutional.\139\
Accordingly, when we refer to states in this final rule, we usually are
referring to both state regulatory authorities and nonregulated
electric utilities.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\137\ See Order No. 69, FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 30,128 at 30,864
(``The implementation of these rules is reserved to the State
regulatory authorities and nonregulated electric utilities.'').
\138\ See Allco Comments at 40.
\139\ Finnerty v. Cowen, 508 F.2d 979, 982 (2d Cir. 1974)
(explaining that administrative agencies ``have neither the power
nor the competence to pass on the constitutionality of
administrative or legislative action'') (quoting Murray v. Vaughn,
300 F. Supp. 688, 695 (D. R.I. 1969)); see also Gibas v. Saginaw
Mining Co., 748 F.2d 1112, 1117 (6th Cir. 1984) (``[A]dministrative
bodies like the Board do not have the authority to adjudicate the
validity of legislation which they are charged with
administering.''); Spiegel, Inc. v. FTC, 540 F.2d 287, 294 (7th Cir.
1976) (finding that the federal agency erred by making a
constitutional determination); Downen v. Warner, 481 F.2d 642, 643
(9th Cir. 1973) (``Resolving a claim founded solely upon a
constitutional right is singularly suited to a judicial forum and
clearly inappropriate to an administrative board.''); cf. Woodrow v.
FERC, 2020 WL 2198050, at *9 (D.D.C. May 6, 2020) (``When Congress
creates an intricate statutory-review process that incorporates
agency consideration and ultimately an avenue to petition an Article
III court, we assume it wants that scheme to control.'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
95. Regarding Public Interest Organizations assertion that the
Commission failed to comply with PURPA section 210's requirement to
consult with federal and state regulatory agencies with ratemaking
authority, we find that the 2016 Technical Conference's invitation to
the public (including state regulatory authorities) to speak, as well
as the notice and comment process on the NOPR itself, encompasses the
required consultation.\140\ The notices soliciting
[[Page 54653]]
comments were open to all state authorities. Indeed, since the
Commission first announced that technical conference and up to our
receipt of comments on the NOPR, representatives from several states
have filed comments expressing their views on how the Commission should
implement PURPA.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\140\ See Notice Inviting Post-Technical Conference Comments,
Implementation Issues Under the Public Utility Regulatory Policies
Act of 1978, Docket No. AD16-16-000 (Sept. 6, 2016); Supplemental
Notice of Technical Conference, Implementation Issues Under the
Public Utility Regulatory Policies Act of 1978, Docket No. AD16-16-
000 (Mar. 4, 2016) (announcing preliminary agenda and inviting
interested speakers).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
B. QF Rates
1. Overview
96. PURPA requires that the Commission promulgate rules, to be
implemented by the states,\141\ that ``shall insure'' that the rates
electric utilities pay for purchases of electric energy from QFs meet
the statutory criteria described above, including that ``[n]o such rule
. . . shall provide for a rate which exceeds'' the purchasing utility's
``incremental cost . . . of alternative electric energy.'' \142\ Under
PURPA, such rates must: (1) Be just and reasonable to the electric
consumers of the electric utility and in the public interest; (2) not
discriminate against qualifying cogenerators or qualifying small power
producers; \143\ and, as noted above, (3) not exceed ``the incremental
cost to the electric utility of alternative electric energy,'' \144\
which is ``the cost to the electric utility of the electric energy
which, but for the purchase from such cogenerator or small power
producer, such utility would generate or purchase from another
source.'' \145\ The ``incremental cost to the electric utility of
alternative electric energy'' referred to in prong (3) above, which
sets out a statutory upper bound on a QF rate, has been consistently
referred to by the Commission and industry by the short-hand phrase
``avoided cost,'' \146\ although the term ``avoided cost'' itself does
not appear in PURPA.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\141\ Nonregulated electric utilities implement the requirements
of PURPA with respect to themselves. An electric utility that is
``nonregulated'' is any electric utility other than a ``state
regulated electric utility.'' 16 U.S.C. 2602(9). The term ``state
regulated electric utility,'' in contrast, means any electric
utility with respect to which a state regulatory authority has
ratemaking authority. 16 U.S.C. 2602(18). The term ``state
regulatory authority,'' as relevant here, means a state agency which
has ratemaking authority with respect to the sale of electric energy
by an electric utility. 16 U.S.C. 2602(17).
\142\ 16 U.S.C. 824a-3(b).
\143\ 16 U.S.C. 824a-3(b)(1)-(2).
\144\ 16 U.S.C. 824a-3(b).
\145\ 16 U.S.C. 824a-3(d) (emphasis added).
\146\ See 18 CFR 292.101(b)(6) (defining avoided costs in
relation to the statutory terms); see also Order No. 69, FERC Stats.
& Regs. ] 30,128 at 30,865 (``This definition is derived from the
concept of `the incremental cost to the electric utility of
alternative electric energy' set forth in section 210(d) of PURPA.
It includes both the fixed and the running costs on an electric
utility system which can be avoided by obtaining energy or capacity
from qualifying facilities.'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
97. In addition, the PURPA Regulations currently provide a QF two
options for how to sell its power to an electric utility. The QF may
choose to sell as much of its energy as it chooses when the energy
becomes available, with the rate for the sale calculated at the time of
delivery (frequently referred to as a so-called ``as-available'' sale
and rate).\147\ Alternatively, the QF may choose to sell pursuant to a
legally enforceable obligation or LEO (such as a contract) over a
specified term.\148\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\147\ 18 CFR 292.304(d)(1).
\148\ 18 CFR 292.304(d)(2)(i)-(ii); see also FLS, 157 FERC ]
61,211 at P 21 (citing 18 CFR 292.304(d)). The LEO or contract is
frequently referred to as a long-term transaction, when contrasted
with an ``as available'' sale and rate.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
98. If the QF chooses to sell under the second option, the PURPA
Regulations then provide the QF the further option of receiving, in
terms of pricing, either: (1) The purchasing electric utility's avoided
cost calculated at the time of delivery; \149\ or (2) the purchasing
electric utility's avoided cost calculated and fixed at the time the
LEO is incurred.\150\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\149\ 18 CFR 292.304(d)(2)(i).
\150\ 18 CFR 292.304(d)(2)(ii). Rates calculated at the time of
a LEO (for example, a contract) do not violate the requirement that
the rates not exceed avoided costs if they differ from avoided costs
at the time of delivery. 18 CFR 292.304(b)(5).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
99. In implementing the PURPA Regulations, the Commission
recognized that a contract with avoided costs calculated at the time a
LEO is incurred could exceed the electric utility's avoided costs at
the time of delivery in the future, thereby seemingly violating PURPA's
requirement that QFs not be paid more than an electric utility's
avoided costs. But the Commission believed that the fixed avoided cost
rate might also turn out to be lower than the electric utility's
avoided costs over the course of the contract and that, ``in the long
run, 'overestimations' and `underestimations' of avoided costs will
balance out.'' \151\ The Commission's justification for allowing QFs to
fix their rate at the time of the LEO for the entire life of the
contract was that fixing the rate provides ``certainty with regard to
return on investment in new technologies.'' \152\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\151\ Order No. 69, FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 30,128 at 30,880. See
also 18 CFR 292.304(b)(5) (``In the case in which the rates for
purchases are based upon estimates of avoided costs over the
specific term of the contract or other legally enforceable
obligation, the rates for such purchases do not violate this subpart
if the rates for such purchases differ from avoided costs at the
time of delivery.''); Entergy Servs., Inc., 137 FERC ] 61,199, at P
56 (2011) (``Many avoided cost rates are calculated on an average or
composite basis, and already reflect the variations in the value of
the purchase in the lower overall rate. In such circumstances, the
utility is already compensated, through the lower rate it generally
pays for unscheduled QF energy, for any periods during which it
purchases unscheduled QF energy even though that energy's value is
lower than the true avoided cost.'').
\152\ Order No. 69, FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 30,128 at 30,880.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
100. In the NOPR, the Commission proposed to revise its PURPA
Regulations to permit states to incorporate competitive market forces
in setting QF rates. Specifically, the Commission proposed to revise
its PURPA Regulations with regard to QF rates to provide states with
the flexibility to:
Require that ``as-available'' QF energy rates paid by
electric utilities located in RTO/ISO markets be based on the market's
LMP, or similar energy price derived by the market, in effect at the
time the energy is delivered.
require that ``as-available'' QF energy rates paid by
electric utilities located outside of RTO/ISO markets be based on
competitive prices determined by: (1) liquid market hub energy prices;
or (2) formula rates based on observed natural gas prices and a
specified heat rate.
require that energy rates under QF contracts and LEOs be
based on as-available energy rates determined at the time of delivery
rather than being fixed for the term of the contract or LEO.
implement an alternative approach of requiring that the
fixed energy rate be calculated based on estimates of the present value
of the stream of revenue flows of future LMPs or other acceptable as-
available energy rates at the time of delivery.
require that energy and/or capacity rates be determined
through a competitive solicitation process, such as an RFP, with
processes designed to ensure that the competitive solicitation is
performed in a transparent, non-discriminatory fashion.\153\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\153\ NOPR, 168 FERC ] 61,184 at PP 32-33.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
101. Although the Commission proposed to modify how the states are
permitted to calculate avoided costs, it did not propose to terminate
the requirement that the states continue to calculate, and to set QF
rates at, such avoided costs.
102. We adopt these proposals in this final rule, with certain
modifications. Each such proposal, and our final determination, is
discussed further below.
2. Use of Competitive Market Prices To Set As-Available Avoided Cost
Rates
103. In addition to commenting on the specific methods for
determining as-available avoided cost rates, several
[[Page 54654]]
commenters addressed more generally the Commission's proposal in the
NOPR that states be given the flexibility to use competitive market
prices to set such rates. Before discussing the specific methods
proposed in the NOPR, we first discuss the determination that the use
of competitive market prices, however determined, can be an appropriate
approach to determining as-available avoided cost rates.
a. NOPR Proposal
104. In the NOPR, the Commission proposed to give the states the
flexibility to use competitive market prices to set as-available
avoided cost rates. The Commission stated its belief that consideration
of transparent, competitive market prices in appropriate circumstances
would help to identify an electric utility's avoided costs in a
simpler, more transparent, and more predictable manner that would, in
conjunction with the Commission's other existing and proposed PURPA
Regulations, act to encourage QFs.\154\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\154\ Id. P 13.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
105. For those utilities located in RTO/ISO markets, the NOPR
identified LMP as a competitive market price that states could choose
to adopt as representing an as-available avoided energy cost. The
Commission explained that LMP could provide an accurate measure of the
varying actual avoided costs for each receipt point on an electric
utility's system where the utility receives power from QFs.\155\ In
addition to these benefits, the Commission observed that LMPs, in
contrast to the administrative pricing methodologies used to set as-
available QF rates by many states, could promote the more efficient use
of the transmission grid, promote the use of the lowest-cost
generation, and provide for transparent price signals.\156\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\155\ Id. P 45.
\156\ Id. P 48 (citing Cal. Indep. Sys. Operator Corp., 105 FERC
] 61,140, at PP 48-50 (2003); Cf. Price Formation in Energy and
Ancillary Servs. Mkts Operated by Reg'l Transmission Orgs. and
Indep. Sys. Operators, 153 FERC ] 61,221, at P 2 (2015)).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
106. For utilities located outside of RTO/ISO markets, the NOPR
proposed to allow states to use two other potential competitively
priced measures of a utility's as-available avoided cost rates: (1)
Energy rates established at liquid market hubs; or (2) energy rates
determined pursuant to formulas based on natural gas price indices and
a proxy heat rate for an efficient natural gas combined-cycle
generating facility. In each such case, though, the state would need to
find that that price reasonably represents a competitive market price
that represents the avoided costs of the purchasing electric
utility.\157\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\157\ NOPR, 168 FERC ] 61,184 at P 51.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
b. Comments
107. Allco argues that the only reason for including the use of
competitive market prices to set as-available energy rates is to create
a menu of prices from which a state regulatory authority or unregulated
electric utility can choose the lowest price. Allco claims this
proposal would not encourage QF generation, would be inconsistent with
the rules of economic dispatch, and would be inconsistent with the
language of PURPA.\158\ BluEarth makes similar arguments.\159\ In
contrast, El Paso Electric argues that state regulatory authorities
should be able to set avoided cost rates based on the lesser of a
market hub price or a combined cycle price.\160\ Similarly, the
California Commission argues that utilities located in organized
markets (not just non-organized markets) should also be expressly
permitted to use any competitive price (whether derived from a market
hub, competitive solicitation, or a combined cycle price) to set
avoided cost rates. The California Commission also argues that states
should have the ability to use competitive prices for not just as-
available energy pricing, but also for capacity pricing, and proposes
minor modifications to the relevant regulation text proposed in the
NOPR in order to clarify these points.\161\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\158\ Allco Comments at 8.
\159\ BluEarth Comments at 2.
\160\ El Paso Electric Comments at 3-4.
\161\ California Commission Comments at 23-27.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
108. The California Commission argues that the proposed regulations
should be modified to: (1) Define the newly permissible avoided cost
methodologies within the definitions section of Part 292; (2) eliminate
any perception that the new methodologies can only be used to set
avoided costs for as-available energy; (3) allow any appropriate
market-based methodology to set avoided-cost rates for energy, capacity
or both; and (4) define ``Organized Electric Market.'' \162\ The
California Commission believes that the new regulations should
indicate: (1) That they do not provide states any more flexibility than
they already have; (2) that utilities located in organized markets may
use any Market Hub Price, Competitive Solicitation Price, or Combined
Cycle Price to establish avoided-cost rates; and (3) that a price based
on LMP or a Competitive Price is just and reasonable and
nondiscriminatory.\163\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\162\ Id. at 11-14.
\163\ Id. at 23-25.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
109. Some commenters object to the use of competitive markets
prices on the grounds that these competitive prices represent only
short-term, or spot prices that do not reflect the long-term marginal
costs and other costs avoided by purchasing utilities.\164\ Similarly,
some commenters assert that competitive prices cannot support the
financing of QFs.\165\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\164\ IdaHydro Comments at 11; Southeast Public Interest
Organizations Comments at 19; NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments
at 52, 55 (citing Exelon Wind I, LLC, 140 FERC ] 61,152, at P 52
(2012)); Union of Concerned Scientists Comments at 6.
\165\ BluEarth Renewables Comments at 2; Biological Diversity at
8; Covanta Comments at 9; Public Interest Organization Comments at
43-44.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
110. Public Interest Organizations argue that using competitive
prices to set as-available energy avoided cost rates is discriminatory
because non-QF generators are not limited to competitive prices and
utilities can, and regularly do, pay effective prices for energy that
exceed the price determined by competitive prices.\166\ Several other
commenters express concern about setting QF prices by referencing
short-term liquid hub prices while allowing utilities to rate base and
recover their long-term investments.\167\ Industrial Energy Consumers
argue that, if the Commission implements the liquid market hub
proposal, there must be assurances that utilities' self-builds face the
same market risk exposure as QFs. For example, they argue, if states
expose QFs to variable rates for their energy output, utility-owned
generation should also be exposed to variable rates for their energy
output.\168\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\166\ Public Interest Organizations Comments at 64.
\167\ IdaHydro Comments at 11; Industrial Energy Consumers
Comments at 12-13.
\168\ Industrial Energy Consumers Comments at 12-13.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
111. Several commenters assert that QF rates should reflect
benefits other than the avoided cost of energy.\169\ For example,
Biogas and Biomass Power state that non-energy benefits, like waste
reduction and economic development must be incorporated into avoided
cost determinations.\170\ Biogas and Resources for the Future state
that locational values should be incorporated into avoided cost
calculations.\171\ American Dams states that utilities' avoided
[[Page 54655]]
transmission charges should be included in avoided cost
determinations.\172\ Xcel states that hidden integration and utility
planning costs should also be incorporated into avoided cost
calculations.\173\ American Dams argues that for high capital projects
like hydro, the Commission should consider longer-term public benefits
and not just short-term market pricing.\174\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\169\ Biogas Comments at 1-2; Biomass Power Comments at 1; EPSA
Comments at 14-16; Resources for the Future Comments at 4; Xcel
Comments at 3-5.
\170\ Biogas Comments at 2; Biomass Power Comments at 1.
\171\ Biogas Comments at 1; Resources for the Future Comments at
4.
\172\ American Dams Comments at 4.
\173\ Xcel Comments at 3-5.
\174\ American Dams Comments at 2.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
112. Solar Energy Industries asserts that payments based on the LMP
should not relieve the purchasing utility of the requirement to
compensate the QF for any values in addition to electricity (e.g.,
renewable energy credits, frequency response capabilities, pro-rated
capacity value, etc.).\175\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\175\ Solar Energy Industry Comments at 27-28.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
113. California Utilities request that the Commission clarify that
states may but are not required to consider state policies when
establishing avoided costs.\176\ Harvard Electricity Law requests that
the Commission clarify its rule allowing states to set tiered
rates.\177\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\176\ California Utilities Comments at 18-19.
\177\ Harvard Electricity Law Comments at 32-33.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
c. Commission Determination
114. As an initial matter, we observe that some of the concerns
raised by commenters about the use of competitive market prices to set
as-available energy rates for QFs are based on the incorrect assumption
that the NOPR proposal would permit states to use competitive market
prices to set as-available energy rates for QFs even when competitive
market prices are below the purchasing utility's avoided costs. In
fact, however, the use of competitive market prices to set QF rates is
explicitly subject to the requirement that such prices are equal to the
purchasing utility's avoided energy costs.\178\ As the Supreme Court
noted in API, the full avoided cost rate requirement represents the
maximum rate permitted under PURPA, and thereby provides important
encouragement to QFs.\179\ And as the Supreme Court also noted in the
same decision, ``the full-avoided-cost rule plainly satisfies the
nondiscrimination requirement.'' \180\ Further, in requiring full
avoided cost rates, ``[t]he Commission did not ignore the interest of
electric utility consumers `in receiving electric energy at equitable
rates.' '' \181\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\178\ Arguments that the various competitive market prices
identified in this final rule do not represent avoided energy costs
are addressed below with respect to each such specific market price.
\179\ API, 461 U.S. at 413.
\180\ Id.
\181\ Id. at 415 (quoting Conf. Rep. at 97).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
115. For this reason, Allco is incorrect when it claims that the
competitive price proposal represents a menu of prices that a state can
select to choose the lowest rate. In the event that more than one
competitive price option potentially could apply, the state would be
required to select the option that reasonably reflects the purchasing
utility's avoided costs, which is what PURPA requires.\182\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\182\ In a competitive market, the transportation costs between
any such two hubs and a QF would be such that they would make the QF
rate the same, no matter which hub was selected. See FERC, Energy
Primer, A Handbook of Market Basics, at 64 (June 2020), https://www.ferc.gov/market-assessments/guide/energy-primer-2020.pdf (Energy
Primer) (``If there are no transmission constraints, or congestion,
LMPs will not vary significantly across the RTO footprint. However,
when transmission congestion occurs, LMPs will vary across the
footprint because operators are not able to dispatch the least-cost
generators across the entire region and some more expensive
generation must be dispatched to meet demand in the constrained
area.'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
116. Further, the record supports the conclusion that the use of
transparent, competitive market prices provides encouragement to QFs,
represents the avoided cost, and can ensure that the rate does not
exceed the incremental cost to the purchasing electric utility. In
addition to the testimony to this effect presented at the technical
conference and cited in the NOPR,\183\ the conclusion is further
supported by comments submitted in response to the NOPR. For example,
NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA cite to a report by Fitch, which explains
how Fitch evaluates the financial strength of renewable energy
projects. In this report, Fitch states that it gives a ``stronger''
evaluation to projects with power sales contract prices that are
``indexed using simple, broad-based publicly available indexation
formulas.'' \184\ In addition, Solar Energy Industries notes the
difficulties QFs face in expending large sums to develop their projects
``[f]or states that do not publish the avoided costs, or for utilities
that treat their avoided cost methodologies as confidential trade
secrets.'' \185\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\183\ See American Forest & Paper Association Comments, Docket
No. AD16-16-000, at 8 (filed June 8, 2016) (``To the extent
possible, these determinations [of avoided costs] should not be made
in a `black box', but rather, as part of an open and transparent
method and process.''); EEI Comments, Docket No. AD16-16-000, at 3
(filed June 30, 2016) (``Where transparent competitive markets with
day ahead prices exist, there is no reason to adhere to second-best
avoided cost pricing mechanisms.'').
\184\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 37-38 (citing
FitchRatings, Global Infrastructure & Project Finance, Renewable
Energy Project Rating Criteria, at 3 (Feb. 26, 2019), https://www.fitchratings.com/site/re/10061770).
\185\ Solar Energy Industries Comments at 41.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
117. We agree with commenters who assert that competitive market
prices represent only short-run spot prices that do not reflect
electric utilities' long-run costs that QFs can displace. However, we
are authorizing states to use competitive market prices only to
establish as-available energy rates for QFs. The comments misunderstand
the fundamental difference between the value to a purchasing utility of
such as-available energy and the value to a purchasing utility of
capacity.
118. A QF has no obligation under the as-available avoided cost
rate provisions to deliver any set amount of electric energy at any
point in the future, but merely is paid for the amount of electric
energy actually delivered. Therefore, the delivery of as-available
energy does not displace any long-term energy the purchasing electric
utility would generate itself or purchase from another source but
rather allows the purchasing utility to reduce the amount of energy it
otherwise would generate itself or purchase from another entity at the
time the QF delivers the energy. Because the QF has no obligation to
deliver any energy in the future, the utility is unable to avoid
constructing or contracting for capacity to meet its future needs as a
consequence of the delivery of energy by the QF. As-available energy
rates therefore appropriately reflect only the short-run value of
energy delivered at the particular moment in time when and if the QF
has energy available to be delivered to the utility.
119. A QF can displace an electric utility's own generation or
purchases from alternative sources over the long-run when a QF sells
capacity to a utility in addition to as-available energy. In contrast
to as-available energy, a sale of capacity would typically compensate
the QF for maintaining the capability to deliver a set amount of energy
in the future (i.e., capital costs),\186\ and thus allows the
purchasing utility to avoid the cost of making alternative
arrangements, either through a self-build or an alternative purchase,
to obtain that amount of energy. Consequently, the price of capacity
purchased from a QF would reflect this long-run avoided cost. And this
final rule does not alter a purchasing utility's
[[Page 54656]]
existing obligation to pay QFs for any avoided capacity benefit that
allows the utility to avoid acquiring capacity.\187\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\186\ See Order No. 69, FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 30,128 at 30,885
(``Energy costs are the variable costs associated with the
production of electric energy (kilowatt-hours). They represent the
cost of fuel, and some operating and maintenance expenses. Capacity
costs are the costs associated with providing the capability to
deliver energy; they consist primarily of the capital costs of
facilities.'').
\187\ See Order No. 69, FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 30,128 at 30,881-
86 (describing how states must calculate avoided capacity costs).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
120. For these reasons, we decline to grant the California
Commission's request to allow using competitive prices for not just as-
available energy pricing, but also for capacity pricing.\188\ We also
reject the California Commission's request to permit all electric
utilities, both those located in organized markets and those located in
non-organized market areas, to use any competitive price (whether a
Market Hub Price or Combined Cycle Price, or alternatively a
Competitive Solicitation Price) to set avoided cost rates. The Market
Hub Price and Combined Cycle Price, as well as the Competitive
Solicitation Price are options that should generally reflect a
purchasing electric utility's avoided as-available energy costs in non-
RTO/ISO areas, while the LMP should generally reflect a purchasing
electric utility's avoided as-available energy costs in RTO/ISO market
areas.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\188\ See infra sections IV.B.3-5. We note that states may use
competitive solicitations to set both energy and capacity avoided
cost rates. See infra section IV.B.8.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
121. With respect to the discrimination claims, our decision to
give states the flexibility to use competitive prices is driven by the
fact that the competitive market price represents the purchasing
utility's avoided costs. And, as explained in Section IV.A.2 above, a
rate set at full avoided costs by definition cannot be discriminatory
and, in any event, the Commission is without authority under PURPA
section 210(b) to require a rate above avoided costs.
122. Further, Industrial Energy Consumers are incorrect when they
suggest that public utility energy rates do not vary with costs in the
same way that the competitive market prices potentially applicable to
QFs under the final rule vary. To the contrary, the Commission and most
states provide for fuel adjustment clauses applicable to rates, which
allow utility rates to adjust automatically with changes in utility
fuel and purchased power costs.\189\ And even utilities whose rates do
not include fuel and purchased power adjustment clauses nevertheless
typically must charge their retail customers cost-based rates, which
means that their energy charges will vary from one rate case to the
next as their fuel and purchased power costs vary from year to year.
These mechanisms for ensuring that utility rates vary with the cost of
energy result in variances in utility energy rates that are similar to
the variance in QF energy rates for those states that elect a
Competitive Price option (either a Market Hub Price or a Combined Cycle
Price) for as-available avoided cost rates.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\189\ See 18 CFR 35.14 (Fuel Cost and Purchased Economic Power
Adjustment Clauses); ELCON, Fuel Adjustment Clauses & Other Cost
Trackers, https://elcon.org/fuel-adjustment-clauses-cost-trackers
(``Fuel adjustment clauses are in effect in almost all states.'');
NARUC, Staff Subcommittee on Accounting and Finance, Fuel and
Purchased Power Survey Results (Sept. 23, 2015), https://pubs.naruc.org/pub/4AA28D50-2354-D714-5149-B773EFC3EFEF (stating
that only one state surveyed said that it did not employ a fuel
adjustment clause).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
123. Finally, although we are sympathetic to the claims of certain
QFs that they provide non-energy benefits (such as environmental
benefits, waste reduction benefits, and economic development benefits)
that are not reflected in avoided cost rates, PURPA section 210(b)
prohibits the Commission from requiring QF rates to be set above full
avoided costs. Because the Commission already requires states to set QF
rates at full avoided costs, it is barred from requiring QF rates set
higher than that based on the non-energy benefits that QFs may also
provide. However, nothing in PURPA, the PURPA Regulations as they
currently exist, or this final rule would prevent states from rewarding
QFs for such non-energy benefits so long as that is done outside of
PURPA, such as is now done for renewable energy credits (RECs) to
compensate QFs for providing unique environmental or other non-PURPA
benefits.\190\ We address in the sections below each type of
competitive price that could be used as an acceptable energy avoided
cost.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\190\ See, e.g., American Ref-Fuel Co., 105 FERC ] 61,004, at PP
22-24 (2003), denying reh'g, 107 FERC ] 61,016 at PP 12, 15-16
(2004), dismissing pet. for review sub nom. Xcel Energy Servs. Inc.
v. FERC, 407 F.3d 1242 (D.C. Cir. 2005).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
3. LMP as a Permissible Rate for Certain As-Available Avoided Cost
Rates
a. NOPR Proposal
124. The Commission proposed to revise 18 CFR 292.304 to add
subsections (b)(6) and (e)(1). In combination, these subsections would
permit a state the flexibility to set the as-available energy rate paid
to a QF by an electric utility located in an RTO/ISO at LMPs calculated
at the time of delivery.
125. The Commission explained that RTO/ISO markets calculate a LMP
at each location on the RTO/ISO-controlled grid, and that all sellers
receive the LMP for their location and all buyers pay the market
clearing price for their location. The Commission further recognized
that LMPs reflect the true marginal cost of production, taking into
account all physical system constraints, and these prices would fully
compensate all resources for the variable cost of providing
service,\191\ and explained that prices in such an LMP-based rate
structure are designed to reflect the least-cost of meeting an
incremental megawatt-hour of demand at each location on the grid in
each period, and thus such prices can vary based on location and
time.\192\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\191\ Offer Caps in Mkts Operated by Reg'l Transmission Orgs.
and Independent Sys. Operators, Order No. 831, 157 FERC ] 61,115, at
P 7 (2016), order on reh'g and clarification, Order No. 831-A, 161
FERC ] 61,156 (2017).
\192\ Sacramento Mun. Util. Dist. v. FERC, 616 F.3d 520, 524
(D.C. Cir. 2010) (SMUD); see also FERC v. Elec. Power Supply Ass'n,
136 S. Ct. 760, 768-69 (2016) (describing how LMP is typically
calculated).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
126. The Commission therefore preliminarily found that LMP is an
accurate measure of avoided costs. Unlike, for example, average system-
wide cost measures of avoided cost used by many states, LMP could
provide an accurate measure of the varying actual avoided costs for
each receipt point on an electric utility's system where the utility
receives power from QFs; LMP is the per MWh cost of obtaining
incremental supplies at each point. Further, the Commission explained
that these prices are not rigid, long-lasting prices as tends to be the
case currently for administratively-determined avoided costs, but
prices that are calculated daily (for the day-ahead markets) and/or
every five minutes (for real-time markets) and they vary to reflect
changing system conditions (e.g., they tend to rise as demand increases
and the system operator dispatches increasingly expensive supplies to
meet that higher demand). In addition, the Commission observed that
LMPs, in contrast to the administrative pricing methodologies used to
set as-available QF rates by many states, could promote the more
efficient use of the transmission grid, promote the use of the lowest-
cost generation, and provide for transparent price signals.\193\
Finally, the Commission also noted that Congress, through enactment of
PURPA section 210(m), appears to have recognized that RTO/ISO LMP
pricing provides sufficient encouragement for QFs.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\193\ See, e.g., Cal. Indep. Sys. Operator Corp., 105 FERC ]
61,140, at PP 48-50 (2003); cf. Price Formation in Energy and
Ancillary Servs. Mkts Operated by Reg'l Transmission Orgs. and
Indep. Sys. Operators, 153 FERC ] 61,221, at P 2.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
127. The Commission requested comment on whether the real-time
prices established in the CAISO-administered Energy Imbalance Market
[[Page 54657]]
(EIM) \194\ are similar for these purposes to the LMP in RTOs/ISOs. In
this regard, the Commission requested comment on whether ``prices
developed in the EIM similarly `reflect the least-cost of meeting an
incremental megawatt-hour of demand at each location on the grid,' as
the Commission has found to be the case with LMP rates.'' \195\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\194\ The Commission noted that, by seeking comment regarding
the Western EIM prices, the Commission did not mean to imply that
real-time energy prices established by CAISO within its balancing
authority area do not already satisfy the requirement for setting
as-available QF rates.
\195\ NOPR, 168 FERC 61,184 at P 47 (quoting SMUD, 616 F.3d at
524). Use of real time prices in the Western EIM was addressed at
the Technical Conference, but only in the context of whether that
market could satisfy the requirements for termination of the
mandatory purchase obligation under PURPA section 210(m)(1)(C). See
Supplemental Notice of Technical Conference, Implementation Issues
Under the Public Utility Regulatory Policies Act of 1978, Docket No.
AD16-16-000 (May 9, 2016). The Commission here requested comments on
whether it would be appropriate to use the Western EIM price to
develop an as-available energy rate.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
128. The Commission understood that some states already use LMP to
establish avoided cost energy rates under the existing PURPA
Regulations.\196\ The Commission thus proposed also to clarify that,
while a state in the past may have been able to conclude that LMP was
an appropriate measure of the energy component of avoided costs,\197\ a
state would, under the proposal in the NOPR, be able to adopt LMP as a
per se appropriate measure of the as-available energy component of
avoided costs.\198\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\196\ See Exelon Wind 1, LLC, 140 FERC ] 61,152, at P 11,
reconsideration denied, 155 FERC ] 61,066 (2016) (recognizing that
the Texas Public Utility Commission has permitted Southwestern
Public Service Company to set avoided costs at LMP); Xcel Energy
Services Inc., Request for Reconsideration, Docket No. EL12-80-001,
at 13 & n.23 (filed Sept. 27, 2012) (stating that Maryland, New
Jersey, North Carolina, Virginia, Connecticut, New Hampshire,
Kentucky, and Michigan have set avoided costs at LMP).
\197\ See 18 CFR 292.304(e).
\198\ The Commission recognized in the NOPR that this proposal
could be seen as a departure from the Commission's statement in
Exelon Wind 1, LLC, 140 FERC ] 61,152 at P 52, reconsideration
denied, 155 FERC ] 61,066 (``The problem with the methodology
proposed by [Southwestern Public Service Company] and adopted by the
Texas Commission is that it is based on the price that a QF would
have been paid had it sold its energy directly in the [Energy
Imbalance Service] Market, instead of using a methodology of
calculating what the costs to the utility would have been for self-
supplied, or purchased, energy `but for' the presence of the QF or
QFs in the markets, as required by the Commission's regulations.'').
The Commission has since found that this statement was overtaken by
events, namely SPP's evolution from an energy imbalance service
market into an Integrated Marketplace, with day-ahead and real-time
energy and operating reserve markets and the Texas Commission's
approving a separate request from Southwestern Public Service
Company to substitute LMP for Locational Imbalance Prices in
calculating avoided costs. Exelon Wind 1, LLC, 155 FERC ] 61,066 at
P 11. The Commission also has acknowledged that, if adopted in a
final rule, the reasoning in the NOPR supported a departure from
precedent. See Cal. Pub. Utils. Comm'n v. FERC, 879 F.3d 966, 977
(9th Cir. 2018) (``When an agency changes policy, the requirement
that it provide a reasoned explanation for its action demands, at a
minimum, that the agency `display awareness that it is changing
position.''') (citing FCC v. Fox Television Stations, Inc., 556 U.S.
502, 515 (2009)).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
b. Comments
i. Comments in Opposition
129. Several commenters oppose the NOPR's LMP proposal.\199\
American Biogas asserts that, by definition, LMP rates assume that
generating facilities are receiving other compensation to fund their
operations and that the marginal rate reflects only the value of the
energy. American Biogas asserts that LMP ignores biogas facilities'
unique municipal infrastructure role and multiple benefits to the
community.\200\ Covanta argues that avoided costs paid to small
baseload QFs should incorporate all long-run avoided costs for capacity
and energy and include other externalities such as the value of
renewable baseload energy, greenhouse gas mitigation, landfill
diversion, reliable and resilient power and other benefits of small
baseload QFs.\201\ Biological Diversity argues that LMP pricing ignores
variability across the country and is inappropriate in regions like the
Southeast which lack RTOs and ISOs and are instead still dominated by
vertically-integrated monopolies.\202\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\199\ Biogas Comments at 2; Covanta Comments at 8-9; Biological
Diversity Comments at 8-9; CA Cogeneration Comments at 8-9; ELCON
Comments at 23-25; ENGIE Comments at 4; New England Small Hydro
Comments at 8-11; NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 53-60;
Public Interest Organizations Comments at 52-64; Union of Concerned
Scientists Comments at 4-9; Southeast Public Interest Organizations
Comments at 21-25.
\200\ Biogas Comments at 2.
\201\ Covanta Comments at 8.
\202\ Biological Diversity Comments at 8-9.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
130. CA Cogeneration argues that LMP may not represent a truly
competitive price for electricity because, in California, the majority
of supply is through bilateral contracts, not through competitive
bidding in the market. CA Cogeneration states that rooftop solar
distorts LMP by reducing load and not bidding in its full long-term
marginal cost.\203\ CA Cogeneration states that LMPs can be well below
the operating cost of conventional generation and combined heat and
power, and even negative, especially when there is an abundance of
procured resources such as hydro, solar, and wind.\204\ CA Cogeneration
asserts that combined heat and power can survive only if: (1) Fixed
capacity prices are sufficiently high to cover the energy price risk;
(2) the market price reflects the full cost of contracted power and
includes all sources of supply; or (3) 18 CFR 292.304(f)(1) is modified
to provide QF operations first priority, except in special
circumstances related to reliability.\205\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\203\ CA Cogeneration Comments at 8-9.
\204\ Id.
\205\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
131. ELCON argues that allowing utilities to use LMP and other
competitive market prices would allow states to ignore long-standing
factors established by Commission regulation in determining the avoided
cost rates, including: (1) Availability of capacity or energy from a QF
during the system daily and seasonal peak periods; (2) dispatchability
and reliability; (3) the relationship of the availability of energy or
capacity from the QF to the ability of the utility to avoid costs; (4)
costs or savings from variations in line losses; and (5) application of
technology-specific avoided cost rates.\206\ ENGIE argues that allowing
states to set energy rates at LMP, while also allowing them to set
capacity rates at zero if it is determined that a utility has no need
for capacity, could allow traditional utilities to corner the market on
capacity, leaving smaller independent QFs to fill energy-only contracts
at LMP.\207\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\206\ ELCON Comments at 23-24.
\207\ ENGIE Comments at 4.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
132. New England Small Hydro states that the Commission has not
supported the NOPR's assertion that LMP is an accurate measure of
avoided costs because the NOPR: (1) Inappropriately relies on the
Energy Policy Act of 2005's changes in PURPA section 210(m) to support
its proposed changes to calculation of the avoided cost rate; (2)
ignores the costs that the utility pays to procure power (i.e., RFPs,
other power contracts, planned retirements); and (3) ignores the fact
that LMP and the default service rates that exist in ISO-NE-based
states are quite different.\208\ In addition, New England Hydro states
that, for the avoided cost calculation, the appropriate LMP is the day-
ahead LMP, not the real-time LMP, because utilities primarily purchase
energy in the day-ahead market pursuant to bilateral contracts or RFPs,
not in the real-time market.\209\ New England Hydro also believes that
utilities or state regulatory bodies should be required to establish
and maintain long-term avoided energy forecasts upon which
[[Page 54658]]
QF PURPA power purchase rates would be based.\210\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\208\ New England Small Hydro Comments at 8-10.
\209\ Id. at 10.
\210\ Id. at 11.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
133. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA claim that LMPs only promote more
efficient use of the transmission grid in the short-term because
factors such as temporary outages, equipment failures, weather
extremes, and the like can cause LMPs to spike, but these have no
impact on long-term transmission availability.\211\ NIPPC, CREA, REC,
and OSEIA believe that, while LMPs are a useful tool for developers to
identify points on the grid where transmission is relatively more or
less congested, developers have strong incentives to avoid congestion,
and they will generally be guided to areas of low congestion during the
transmission interconnection process, whether or not they face LMP-
based contract prices. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA claim that if
transmission constraints prevent a generator from delivering power to a
specific node, the LMP at that node cannot be an appropriate measure of
costs avoided by purchase of power from that generator. NIPPC, CREA,
REC, and OSEIA argue that LMP or Western EIM prices at the time of
delivery are not a true measure of the long-term avoided costs of
incumbent utilities unless those utilities are relying on those markets
as a means to obtain long-term resources.\212\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\211\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 57-59.
\212\ Id. at 55 (citing Exelon Wind I, 140 FERC ] 61,152 at P
52).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
134. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA assert that the NOPR proposal
fails to recognize: (1) the Commission's struggle to develop effective
capacity markets in the RTO/ISO regions; (2) the fact that the merchant
generation model is now in serious question; and (3) that the
Commission's claim that Congress endorsed the use of LMP to set avoided
cost rates by adoption of section 210(m) cannot be squared with the
plain language of the statute.\213\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA argue
that there is substantial evidence that LMP prices are distorted by
certain practices, such as zero-cost bids, so that plants operate
uneconomically.\214\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA further maintain that
the 2000-01 California market demonstrated that these volatile short-
term markets can reach extreme and unpredictable highs under stress
conditions.\215\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\213\ Id. at 57-59.
\214\ Id. at 55.
\215\ Id. at 57.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
135. Similarly, Public Interest Organizations cite to studies by
the Sierra Club \216\ and Bloomberg New Energy Finance,\217\ for the
proposition that the use of LMP as the QF price discriminates against
QFs where utility-owned generation and non-QF generators are not
limited to the LMP for recovery of their costs, and where utilities
depress LMP through uneconomic dispatch of their own generation
facilities.\218\ Union of Concerned Scientists states that LMPs are not
an accurate measure of avoided costs and should not be used to set QF
rates because the practice of providing utility-owned generation with
out-of-market cost-recovery in areas like MISO, PJM, SPP, the SERC
Reliability Corporation, and the Western Electricity Coordinating
Council suppresses the clearing prices in the markets where this is
allowed.\219\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\216\ Public Interest Organizations Comments at 53-56 (citing
Jeremy Fisher, Sierra Club, Playing with Other People's Money, How
Non-Economic Coal Operations Distort Energy Markets, Sierra Club,
Oct. 2019, at 4).
\217\ Id. at 57 (citing William Nelson & Sophia Liu, Half of
U.S. Coal Fleet on Shaky Economic Footing; Coal Plant Operating
Margins Nationwide, Bloomberg New Energy Finance, March 26, 2018).
\218\ Id. at 52-64.
\219\ Union of Concerned Scientists Comments at 3-8.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
136. Southeast Public Interest Organizations argue that the NOPR's
proposed avoided cost methodology does not take into account: (1) Long-
term or seasonal purchases made from third parties or affiliates; (2)
adjustments for transmission and distribution losses; (3) capacity
deferrals; (4) avoided environmental compliance costs; or (5) a QF's
dispatchability.\220\ Southeast Public Interest Organizations state
that LMP-based rates for QFs in Virginia have enticed little-to-no QF
development in Virginia.\221\ Southeast Public Interest Organizations
urge the Commission either to rescind the NOPR's LMP provisions or at
least to implement this provision on a case-by-case basis.\222\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\220\ Southeast Public Interest Organizations Comments at 22.
\221\ Id. at 23.
\222\ Id. at 24.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
(a) Utilizing Western EIM To Establish Avoided Costs
137. Solar Energy Industries argues that, because as-available QF
resources are not eligible to participate in the Western EIM (also
known as the CAISO EIM), either directly or through the purchasing
utility, it would be inappropriate to use the Western EIM price as a
proxy because that market does not factor in the participation of the
QF resource.\223\ ELCON asserts that the Western EIM is not a complete
measure of avoided energy costs because the Western EIM merely covers
imbalance conditions, and therefore does not capture the vast majority
of unit commitment and dispatch scheduling cost parameters.\224\ Union
of Concerned Scientists asserts that allowing a state to adopt real-
time prices established in the Western EIM as an accurate measure of
avoided costs will be discriminatory.\225\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\223\ Solar Energy Industries Comments at 27.
\224\ ELCON Comments at 24.
\225\ Union of Concerned Scientists Comments at 9.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
ii. Comments in Support
138. Several commenters support the Commission's proposal to permit
a state the flexibility to use LMPs to set the as-available energy rate
paid to a QF by an electric utility located in an RTO/ISO.\226\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\226\ APPA Comments at 11; Arizona Public Service Comments at 5;
CA Utilities Comments at 17; Conn. Authority Comments at 13; DTE
Electric Comments at 4; EEI Comments at 22-24; Comments at 4-5;
Idaho Commission Comments at 3-4; Indiana Municipal Comments at 5;
Kentucky Commission Comments at 4-5; NorthWestern Comments at 4-7;
NRECA Comments at 6-7; Ohio Commission Energy Advocate Comments at
4-5; Pennsylvania Commission Comments at 7-9; South Dakota
Commission Comments at 2; US Chamber of Commerce Comments at 4; We
Stand Comments at 1; Xcel Comments at 5.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
139. CA Utilities state that the NOPR's LMP proposal is a return to
the Commission's policy as expressed in Winding Creek,\227\ and will
facilitate payments to QFs that more accurately represent a utility's
actual avoided costs. CA Utilities assert that the NOPR's LMP proposal
affirms that a formula energy price contract complies with PURPA if
coupled with a fixed capacity price. CA Utilities state that a formula
energy price contract will have the additional benefit of avoiding the
need to develop and administer a new PURPA contract.\228\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\227\ CA Utilities Comments at 15-17 (citing Winding Creek Solar
LLC, 151 FERC ] 61,103, at P 6 (2015)).
\228\ Id. at 17.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
140. NRECA supports the Commission's proposal because many
utilities that participate in the RTO/ISO markets offer the entirety of
their generation into the market, and purchase all of their
requirements to serve load from that market, at LMP prices.\229\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\229\ NRECA Comments at 6.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
141. The Pennsylvania Commission supports the NOPR proposal because
LMP prices vary through the day based on changing system conditions,
such as changes in electricity demand, supply, congestion, and line
losses. The Pennsylvania Commission asserts that, because some
utilities in Pennsylvania
[[Page 54659]]
(and other states) have already incorporated LMP elements in their as-
available energy rates, a corresponding revision to the Commission's
regulations that incorporates such practices and harmonizes state and
federal regulations would bring greater predictability to suppliers,
electric utilities and customers.\230\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\230\ Pennsylvania Commission Comments at 7-8.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
142. The Ohio Commission Energy Advocate believes that, in the
parts of the country with organized nodal wholesale electricity
markets, LMP is an appropriate and fair means by which to calculate
avoided costs because electricity supply and demand must be balanced in
real time. The Ohio Commission Energy Advocate notes that Ohio has
nodal LMPs that reflect the true value of energy at the place and the
time it is produced or delivered, and this value can change
dramatically, even within a day or an hour. The Ohio Commission Energy
Advocate concludes that reflecting the dynamic nature of electricity
pricing in avoided cost calculations will send the most accurate price
signals to QFs and will appropriately and fairly value the energy they
produce.\231\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\231\ Ohio Commission Energy Advocate Comments at 4-5.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
143. The South Dakota Commission supports using LMP for certain as-
available QF energy sales because using LMP will increase states'
flexibility. The South Dakota Commission regulates six vertically
integrated electric utilities, five of which are RTO members, and five
of which are multi-jurisdictional.\232\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\232\ South Dakota Commission Comments at 2.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
144. Xcel submits that compensating QFs based on LMPs at the time
of delivery will not impair QFs' ability to obtain financing because
other factors can drive the ability to obtain financing, including
other project options, location, size, interconnection costs,
experience of the developer, current economic conditions,
creditworthiness of the developer, economies of scale, and other
factors. Xcel states that some resource specific information generally
suggests that the right project in the right location can obtain
financing if the project receives hourly payment based on LMPs.\233\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\233\ Xcel Comments at 5-7.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
(a) Utilizing Western EIM To Establish Avoided Costs
145. NorthWestern and EIM Entities agree that the Western EIM real-
time prices are similar to LMPs and reflect the least cost of meeting
an incremental megawatt-hour of demand at each location on the
grid.\234\ Xcel asserts that prices in the Western EIM are calculated
using the same methodology as LMPs because, in both cases, units are
dispatched on a least-cost basis that respects applicable transmission
constraints. Xcel requests that the Commission allow avoided costs to
be based on Western EIM prices at the time of delivery absent a showing
that prices would be suppressed in comparison to an LMP-style-
market.\235\ Arizona Public Service states that it is a participant in
the Western EIM, and requests that states be given flexibility to set
the as-available energy rate to be paid to a QF by an electric utility
that participates in the Western EIM at the LMP.\236\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\234\ EIM Entities Comments at 2-3, 7-13; NorthWestern Comments
at 4-5.
\235\ Xcel Comments at 7-8.
\236\ Arizona Public Service Comments at 5-6.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
iii. Comments in Support With Requested Modifications/Clarifications
146. APPA urges the Commission to clarify that nothing in the
proposed rule is intended to call into question state regulatory
authorities' existing implementation of PURPA's avoided cost
requirements, such as their existing use of LMP.\237\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\237\ APPA Comments at 9.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
147. Industrial Energy Consumers do not object to the use of LMP as
the avoided cost rate for electric utilities' purchases of QF energy in
RTO/ISO regions,\238\ but they maintain that in non-RTO/ISO regions,
there must be assurance that utilities' self-builds face the same
market risk exposure as QFs.\239\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\238\ Industrial Energy Consumers Comments at 11.
\239\ Id. at 12.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
148. The Kentucky Commission supports the NOPR's LMP proposal but
prefers that the Commission in the final rule allow states to determine
whether the LMP calculation should use the generator LMP or the load
LMP on a case-by-case basis.\240\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\240\ Kentucky Commission Comments at 4-5.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
149. Solar Energy Industries assert that, where the purchasing
utility has demonstrated that it procures its marginal energy from an
LMP market, the utility may use the LMP price as a proxy for avoided
energy costs calculated at the time the obligation is incurred, so long
as there are published prices at the location.\241\ Solar Energy
Industries request that the Commission make clear that: (1) The
flexibility to set QF payment rates for as-available energy at the
applicable LMP requires an on-the record determination that the
purchasing utility procures incremental energy from the identified LMP
market at those prices; (2) payments based on an LMP do not relieve the
purchasing utility of the requirement to compensate the QF for any
values in addition to electricity (e.g., renewable energy credits,
frequency response capabilities, pro-rated capacity value, etc.); and
(3) the state's flexibility to allow utilities to set QF payment rates
for as-available energy at the applicable LMP does not in any way limit
QFs' rights to establish a LEO or contract for a longer-term sale at
fixed, full avoided costs.\242\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\241\ Solar Energy Industries Comments at 25-26.
\242\ Id. at 27-28.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
150. NorthWestern believes that as-available rates based on LMPs
should accurately capture current events impacting prices, including
times when there is a high saturation of energy available causing
prices to be negative. However, NorthWestern believes that it is
appropriate to deduct from the avoided cost rate the cost for ancillary
services to balance and integrate energy resources.\243\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\243\ NorthWestern Comments at 4-5.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
c. Commission Determination
151. We affirm with one modification the NOPR proposal to allow LMP
to be used as a measure of as-available energy avoided costs for
electric utilities located in RTO/ISO markets for the reasons set forth
in the NOPR \244\ and those provided by various commenters.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\244\ NOPR, 168 FERC ] 61,184 at PP 44-45.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
152. We recognize that an LMP selected by a state to set a
purchasing utility's avoided energy cost component might not always
reflect a purchasing utility's actual avoided energy costs.
Accordingly, we find that it is appropriate to modify the option for a
state to set avoided energy costs using LMP from a per se appropriate
measure of avoided cost to a rebuttable presumption that LMP is an
appropriate means to determine avoided cost. While a state could rely
on the presumption, an aggrieved entity (such as a QF) may attempt to
rebut the presumption that LMP reflects the purchasing electric
utility's avoided costs. The aggrieved entity would be able to
challenge the state's decision to rely on LMP in the appropriate forum,
which could include any one or more of the following: (1) Initiating or
participating in proceedings before the relevant state commission or
governing body; (2) filing for judicial review of any state regulatory
proceeding in state court (under PURPA section 210(g)); or,
alternatively (3)) filing a petition for enforcement against the state
at the Commission and, if the Commission declines to act, later filing
a petition against the state in U.S.
[[Page 54660]]
district court (under PURPA section 210(h)(2)(B)).\245\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\245\ See Policy Statement Regarding the Commission's
Enforcement Role Under Section 210 of the Public Utility Regulatory
Policies Act of 1978, 23 FERC ] 61,304.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
153. Commenters have not persuaded us that LMP may not
presumptively reflect a purchasing electric utility's avoided energy
costs. LMP sets day-ahead and real-time energy prices through
competitive auctions in RTOs/ISOs that optimally dispatch resources to
balance supply and demand, while taking into account actual system
conditions including congestion on the transmission system. We continue
to find that: (1) LMPs reflect the true marginal cost of production of
energy, taking into account all physical system constraints; (2) these
prices would fully compensate all resources for their variable cost of
providing service; (3) LMP prices are designed to reflect the least-
cost of meeting an incremental megawatt-hour of demand at each location
on the grid, and thus prices vary based on location and time; and (4)
unlike average system-wide cost measures of the avoided energy cost
used by many states, LMP should provide a more accurate measure of the
varying actual avoided energy costs, hour by hour, for each receipt
point on an electric utility's system where the utility receives power
from QFs.\246\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\246\ See NOPR, 168 FERC ] 61,184 at PP 44-45 (citing SMUD, 616
F.3d at 524; FERC v. Elec. Power Supply Ass'n, 136 S. Ct. at 768-69
(describing how LMP is typically calculated); Order No. 831, 157
FERC ] 61,115, at P 7, order on reh'g and clarification, Order No.
831-A, 161 FERC ] 61,156).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
154. Various commenters have provided additional reasons for
supporting the NOPR proposal concerning LMP. NRECA explains that LMP
rates for energy are appropriate because many utilities that
participate in the RTO/ISO markets offer the entirety of their
generation into the market at LMP prices and buy all of their load
requirements from the market at LMP prices.\247\ This scenario
described by NRECA is a common one, and it demonstrates that the market
itself, with its LMP pricing, can be the electric utility resource that
would be displaced by a QF purchase. Furthermore, as argued by
Pennsylvania Commission, because some utilities in Pennsylvania and
other states have already incorporated LMP in their as-available energy
rates, a corresponding revision to the Commission's regulations that
incorporates such practices and harmonizes state and federal
regulations would bring greater predictability to suppliers, electric
utilities and customers.\248\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\247\ NRECA Comments at 6.
\248\ Pennsylvania Commission Comments at 7-8.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
i. Arguments Against the NOPR Proposal
155. Commenters have not offered persuasive arguments for rejecting
the use of LMP for avoided cost energy rate determination. We disagree
with the argument made by Union of Concerned Scientists,\249\ NIPPC,
CREA, REC, and OSEIA,\250\ and Public Interest Organizations \251\ that
LMP should not be used as a measure of avoided energy costs because LMP
prices are depressed in many markets where self-scheduling rights and
state cost-recovery mechanisms for fuel and operating costs create the
opportunity for market participation at a loss. We recognize that, all
other things being equal, self-scheduling of resources may impact
market clearing prices. This potential price effect, however, does not
mean that the LMP is not an accurate measure of avoided energy costs.
The Commission's regulations, using language from PURPA section 210(d),
define avoided costs as ``the incremental costs to an electric utility
of electric energy or capacity or both which, but for the purchase from
the qualifying facility or qualifying facilities, such electric utility
would generate for itself or purchase from another source.'' \252\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\249\ Union of Concerned Scientists Comments at 3-8.
\250\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 52.
\251\ Public Interest Organizations Comments 52-64.
\252\ 18 CFR 292.101(b)(6) (emphasis added).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
156. In organized wholesale electric market areas, the electric
utility purchases that would be displaced by QF purchases would, as
NRECA explains, in all likelihood be priced at the relevant LMP. These
LMPs are impacted by many factors, such as self-scheduling, generator
outages, and transmission outages, that may result in LMPs that are
lower or higher than they might otherwise have been. Thus, while self-
scheduling or other factors may impact LMPs, in any case, an electric
utility's purchases during periods when these price impacts are
occurring would be made at the resulting LMPs, whatever those LMPs may
be. Therefore, LMPs meet the Commission's long-standing definition of
avoided costs for a purchasing electric utility, even if they happen to
reflect price impacts from self-scheduling or other factors.
157. Furthermore, while commenters discuss the possibility that
utility-owned coal-fired resources are self-scheduling only because
retail ratepayers are subsidizing such activities, even if such claims
were true they would not alter the above analysis. The LMPs that result
from a market that includes self-scheduled resources still represent
the price of purchases in the market that would be displaced by the QF
purchase.
158. In addition, we reject the related request for clarification
made by Solar Energy Industries,\253\ i.e., that the flexibility to set
QF payments for as-available energy at the applicable LMP should
require an on-the-record determination that the purchasing utility
procures incremental energy from the identified LMP market at those
prices. Unless an aggrieved entity seeks to rebut this presumption in a
state avoided cost adjudication, rulemaking, legislative determination,
or other proceeding, that state would not need to make such an on-the-
record determination before it decides to use LMP.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\253\ Solar Energy Industry Comments at 27-28.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
159. Entities may seek to rebut the presumption in particular
cases, as described earlier, and whether the utility actually procures
energy from the identified LMP market or from resources with prices
tied to the identified LMP may be a relevant factor in such rebuttal
arguments. Consistent with the reasons described above for why there
should be such a rebuttable presumption in favor of LMP, this
delineation of rights appropriately places the initial burden on
entities seeking to rebut the presumption, rather than on the states
who wish to rely on LMP for setting avoided cost rates for as-available
energy. The Commission could consider such issues if and when they may
arise in individual cases appropriately brought to the Commission,
including whether the state has adequately justified its use of that
rebuttable presumption.
160. We reject the arguments made by NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA
that, more generally, prices for long-term QF contracts should be set
by reference to long-term price indices or other indicators that
genuinely reflect the long-term costs of generation avoided by the
purchasing utility.\254\ This final rule only addresses as-available
energy, and as-available energy prices by definition are short term, as
explained below in Section IV.B.7.c.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\254\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 53.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
161. We also reject the arguments made by NIPPC, CREA, REC, and
OSEIA that, while the NOPR is correct that LMPs are intended to promote
more efficient use of the transmission grid,
[[Page 54661]]
that is true only in the short term since factors such as temporary
outages, equipment failures, weather extremes, and the like can cause
LMPs to spike, but these have no impact on long-term transmission
availability. LMPs promote efficient use of the transmission grid in
the long term as well as the short term. Persistence of significant
price separation between different LMP nodes provides an indication of
the value of various possible transmission system upgrades and can show
transparently how system efficiencies may be improved by such
transmission system upgrades. Developers may have some incentive to
avoid congestion without LMPs, but LMPs provide an important price
signal as to how economic or uneconomic a particular production site
may be. In any event, the potential for more efficient use of the
transmission grid is merely an additional benefit of using LMP for
avoided energy cost determinations. Our adoption of LMP as a measure of
avoided energy costs in the RTO/ISO markets is based principally on the
fact that, in RTO/ISO markets, LMP accurately represents the purchasing
electric utility's avoided energy cost at the time the energy is
delivered, for the reasons described earlier.
162. We also are not persuaded by arguments that, if transmission
constraints prevent a generator from delivering power to a specific
node, the LMP at that node cannot be an appropriate measure of costs
avoided by purchase of power from that generator. As discussed above,
an avoided cost rate should reflect not only the cost of energy that
was avoided by the purchasing electric utility, but also the cost to
deliver the QF energy to the purchasing electric utility's load, such
that the total cost avoided is reflected in the rate. In an RTO/ISO
market, a state appropriately is entitled to consider whether the cost
of delivery from the QF node to the load node (including any redispatch
costs necessary to facilitate such delivery over a system that is
otherwise constrained between those nodes) should be reflected in the
LMP at the QF supply node. In instances commenters refer to where
transmission constraints prevent a generator from delivering power to a
specific node, we disagree that such delivery is actually
``prevented.'' Rather, redispatch of system resources would be
necessary to facilitate the delivery, and the respective LMPs reflect
those redispatch costs.
163. We also reject the argument made by NIPPC, CREA, REC, and
OSEIA that the 2000-01 California market demonstrated that volatile
short-term markets can reach extreme and unpredictable highs under
stress conditions.\255\ First we note that, in the wake of the 2000-
2001 California energy crisis, all RTO/ISO markets developed more
comprehensive ex ante market power mitigation measures than existed in
CAISO at that time, including offer caps and reference level
replacement offers, meant in part to moderate such extremes.\256\ In
any event, any price volatility that may currently exist in LMP
markets, regardless of the reason for the price volatility, and
regardless of whether the volatility causes LMPs to be lower or higher,
nevertheless accurately represents the avoided cost of the purchasing
electric utilities in those markets in those hours, as explained
elsewhere in this final rule.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\255\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 57. Curiously,
these commenters here essentially take the position that higher LMPs
and resulting higher avoided cost energy rates, which would normally
seem to be beneficial to QFs, are instead now anathema.
\256\ See generally Wholesale Competition in Regions with
Organized Elec. Mkts., Order No. 719, 125 FERC ] 61,071 (2008),
order on reh'g, Order No. 719-A, 128 FERC ] 61,059, order on reh'g,
Order No. 719-B, 129 FERC ] 61,252 (2009).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
164. Finally, we remain convinced that Congress recognized that
RTO/ISO LMP pricing provides sufficient encouragement for QFs through
the enactment of PURPA section 210(m) with its directive that,
essentially, the mandatory purchase obligation can be lifted upon QFs
having non-discriminatory access to RTO/ISO markets. As noted earlier,
however, our decision to grant states the flexibility to rely on a
rebuttable presumption that RTO/ISO LMP pricing is an appropriate
measure of avoided energy costs (and thus set as-available energy rates
in reliance on LMPs) reflects our view that, in RTO/ISO markets, as a
general matter LMP indeed accurately represents the purchasing electric
utility's avoided energy costs.
165. We also disagree with ELCON's \257\ argument that LMP should
not be used to measure avoided costs because that would allow states to
ignore long-standing factors established by the Commission that should
be used to determine avoided costs. The factors referenced by ELCON are
relevant to the traditional administrative determination of avoided
cost, and our revisions to the regulations preserve these factors for
that purpose and for avoided capacity costs. If a state chooses instead
to rely on LMP to set avoided energy cost rates, then it will
necessarily not be using those administrative means of determining
avoided costs, and these factors thus will not be relevant.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\257\ ELCON Comments at 23-24.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
166. We are not persuaded by the arguments of various commenters
that LMP cannot be used for avoided cost rates because it ignores the
unique municipal infrastructure role and the multiple benefits of the
community of biogas facilities,\258\ including the value of renewable
baseload energy, greenhouse gas mitigation, landfill diversion,
reliable and resilient power and other benefits of small baseload
QFs.\259\ PURPA frames the determination of QF rates in terms of
avoided cost and does not authorize the Commission in determining QF
rates, particularly as-available energy rates, to consider non-energy-
related factors such as a generator's unique municipal infrastructure
role, greenhouse gas mitigation, and landfill diversion.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\258\ Biogas Comments at 2.
\259\ Covanta Comments at 8.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
167. We also are not persuaded by the argument of CA Cogeneration
that LMP may not represent a truly competitive price for electricity in
California since the majority of California supply is through bilateral
contracts, not through competitive bidding in the market, and that
other factors also distort LMP such as roof top solar. CA Cogeneration,
in essence, objects to the state of California's decision to award
preferred resource status to some resources, such as solar and wind,
and not others, such as cogeneration. These are procurement decisions
made at the state level in connection with resource planning and retail
ratemaking. Even if those decisions impact the resulting LMPs, as CA
Cogeneration claims, that impact would not invalidate the arguments
made above for why LMP is presumptively an appropriate measure of as-
available energy avoided costs in RTO/ISO markets. The aggrieved entity
would be able to challenge the state's decision to rely on LMP in the
appropriate forum, which could include any one or more of the
following: (1) Initiating or participating in proceedings before the
relevant state commission or governing body; (2) filing for judicial
review of any state regulatory proceeding in state court (under PURPA
section 210(g)); or, alternatively (3) filing a petition for
enforcement against the state at the Commission and, if the Commission
declines to act, later filing a petition against the state in U.S.
district court (under PURPA section 210(h)(2)(B)).\260\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\260\ See Policy Statement Regarding the Commission's
Enforcement Role Under Section 210 of the Public Utility Regulatory
Policies Act of 1978, 23 FERC ] 61,304.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
[[Page 54662]]
168. We reject the argument made by New England Small Hydro that
the Commission has not supported its view that LMP is an accurate
measure of avoided costs since LMP ignores the costs that the utility
pays to procure power, including through competitive solicitations,
other power contracts, planned retirements and other factors that are
considered in a utility's long-term plans; and ignores the fact that
LMP and the default service rates that exist in ISO-NE-based states are
quite different.\261\ The costs that a purchasing utility pays to
procure power, including through competitive solicitations, other power
contracts, planned retirements and other factors that are considered in
a utility's long-term plans may be relevant to the utility's purchase
of capacity using long-term contracts, but not to the determination of
the proper as-available energy avoided cost rate to be paid to QFs,
which rates will necessarily vary as system conditions vary over time,
as reflected by variances in LMP over time. The fact that LMP and the
default service rates that exist in ISO-NE-based states may diverge is
to be expected because the latter, unlike the as-available energy rates
charged by QFs in RTO/ISO markets that LMP is being used to price,
normally include transmission and distribution costs (and possibly firm
supplier capacity costs) necessary to ensure that firm supply is
continually available to residential customers.\262\ While utilities or
state regulatory authorities continue to have the authority to
establish and maintain long-term avoided energy forecasts upon which QF
PURPA power purchase rates may be based, and to recognize the actual
future energy costs incorporated in new power contracts that are being
signed by New England utilities, elsewhere in this final rule the
Commission explains why the use of variable prices can be appropriate
for long-term energy contracts.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\261\ New England Small Hydro Comments at 8-10.
\262\ Compare ISO-NE, Transmission, Markets, and Services
Tariff, LMPs and Real-Time Reserve Clearing Prices Calculation,
Sec. III.2.5 (describing how nodal real-time prices are calculated
in ISO-NE at each node using energy offers and bids, transmission
constraints, and other factors) with National Grid, Investigation as
to the Propriety of Proposed Tariff Changes, Docket No. DPU 18-150,
Exh. NG-HSG-1, Gorman Test. 3:18-4:6 (Nov. 15, 2018), https://fileservice.eea.comacloud.net/FileService.Api/file/FileRoom/10043215
(``The Company's filing is based on its investments and costs
incurred to provide distribution service to its customers. An
[Allocated Cost of Service Study] directly assigns or allocates each
element of the revenue requirement, including plant and other
investments, operating expenses, depreciation and taxes, among the
rate classes, in order to determine the costs of providing service
to each rate class. Each element of the total revenue requirement is
analyzed and assigned to or allocated among the rate classes, so the
utility can establish rates that, subject to assumptions such as
kilowatt-hour (`kWh') delivery volumes and the number of customers,
provide it with a fair opportunity to recover its costs and to earn
an appropriate return.'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
169. We are not persuaded by the argument of Southeast Public
Interest Organizations that the NOPR does not establish a framework for
just and reasonable and nondiscriminatory rates because the proposed
avoided cost methodology does not take into account any long-term or
seasonal purchases made from third parties or affiliates, adjustments
for transmission and distribution losses, capacity deferrals, avoided
environmental compliance costs, or dispatchability of the QF.\263\ LMP
pricing, in fact, does reflect transmission and distribution losses.
The other factors that the Southeast Public Interest Organizations
mention here, such as environmental compliance costs, dispatchability,
long-term or seasonal purchases and capacity deferrals, are factors
that are more applicable to the pricing of capacity and long-term
contracts, not the pricing of as-available energy, which is what the
Commission's NOPR proposal as adopted in this final rule addresses.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\263\ Southeast Public Interest Organizations Comments at 22.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
170. The Commission rejects the argument made by Biological
Diversity \264\ that LMP pricing ignores the variability of conditions
across the country. LMP prices by definition vary as supply, demand,
and system conditions change across the country. In any event, the
Commission agrees that LMP pricing would not currently be applicable in
regions like the Southeast that lack RTOs and ISOs and thus that do not
use LMP.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\264\ Biological Diversity Comments at 8-9.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
171. We further reject the argument made by ENGIE that allowing
states to set energy rates using LMPs combined with the ability to set
capacity rates at zero if it is determined that a utility has no need
for capacity has the potential to allow traditional utilities to corner
the market on capacity, leaving smaller independent QFs to provide only
energy-only service.\265\ PURPA does not direct the Commission to
guarantee that QF sales make up some specified share of utilities'
capacity needs nor does it require that each QF receive compensation
for providing capacity. PURPA instead focuses on the purchasing
electric utility's avoided costs and provides that the Commission
cannot require that prices charged by a QF exceed the purchasing
electric utility's avoided cost, if a purchasing electric utility has
no need for additional capacity (and thus the purchasing utility's
avoided cost for capacity would be zero),\266\ the only service that
QFs (and other suppliers) would need to provide that utility is energy.
However, a utility's ability to ``corner the market'' on capacity
depends not uniquely on the pricing of QF sales to the utility, but on
a host of factors including the utility's analysis of its need for
capacity and, without a specific inquiry into the circumstances of each
utility, it cannot be concluded that any utility's decision will always
be deficient or that it has been adversely and inappropriately affected
by the Commission's action here.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\265\ ENGIE Comments at 4.
\266\ See, e.g., NOPR, 168 FERC ] 61,184 at P 33 n.58; see also
City of Ketchikan, Alaska, 94 FERC ] 61,293 at 62,061 (2001)
(``[A]voided cost rates need not include the cost for capacity in
the event that the utility's demand (or need) for capacity is zero.
That is, when the demand for capacity is zero, the cost for capacity
may also be zero.'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
172. Several commenters maintain that reliance on LMP will make it
difficult for QFs to obtain financing.\267\ This argument is addressed
below in section IV.B.7 of this final rule.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\267\ Biogas Comments at 2; BluEarth Renewables Comments at 2;
Biological Diversity at 8; Covanta Comments at 9; Distributed Sun
Comments at 1-2; New England Small Hydro Comments at 10; NIPPC,
CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 53.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
ii. Requests for Modification or Clarification of the NOPR
173. We will not provide the clarifications requested by New
England Small Hydro that the Commission require the use of the day-
ahead LMP for QF rates set at LMP, or Southeast Public Interest
Organizations' request to require the use of real-time LMP rather than
average LMP. States that choose to use LMP will determine the LMP most
representative of the avoided cost of the relevant purchasing utility.
174. While the Kentucky Commission requests that the Commission
allow the use of the LMP at a delivery (load) node rather than a
receipt (generator or QF) node, we find that this decision should be
made by the state as it determines which particular LMP best reflects
the avoided cost of the purchasing electric utility.
175. We grant APPA's request for clarification that, while the NOPR
provides greater clarity as to states' entitlement to rely on
competitively-set prices as a measure of avoided cost rates, nothing in
the final rule is intended to call into question any particular state's
existing implementation of PURPA's avoided cost requirements, such as
their existing use of LMP.\268\ While in the past a state
[[Page 54663]]
may have been able to conclude that LMP was an appropriate measure of
the avoided cost for energy, a state can now also rely on a rebuttable
presumption that LMP is an appropriate measure of the as-available
avoided cost for energy to be used in determining a QF's as-available
avoided cost energy rate.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\268\ APPA Comments at 9.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
176. We provide the following clarification in response to the
Solar Energy Industries' request that the Commission make clear that
payments based on LMP do not relieve the purchasing utility of the
requirement to compensate the QF for any values in addition to
electricity (e.g., RECs, etc.), and that the state's flexibility to
allow utilities to set QF payment rates for as-available energy at the
applicable LMP does not in any way limit QFs' rights to establish a LEO
or contract for a longer-term sale at fixed, full avoided costs.\269\
In Windham Solar LLC,\270\ the Commission summarized its precedent
concerning RECs. The Commission stated that the states have the
authority to determine who owns RECs in the initial instance and how
they are transferred, and that the automatic transfer of RECs within a
sale of power at wholesale must find its authority in state law, not
PURPA. But the Commission also held that a state may not assign
ownership of RECs to utilities based on a logic that the avoided cost
rates in PURPA contracts already compensate QFs for RECs in addition to
compensating QFs for energy and capacity, because under PURPA the
avoided cost rates are, in fact, compensation just for energy and
capacity.\271\ We see no reason to disturb that precedent in this final
rule. With regard to the right of QFs to establish a LEO, that right is
neither limited nor expanded by a state's choice of LMP as the measure
of avoided costs for energy.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\269\ Solar Energy Industry Comments at 27-28.
\270\ 156 FERC ] 61,042 (2016).
\271\ Id. P 4.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
iii. Western EIM
177. We hereby find that the Western EIM prices, like other LMP
prices, may presumptively be used as a measure of as-available energy
avoided costs for utilities able to participate in the Western EIM
market. As Xcel points out, ``prices in the EIM are calculated using
the same methodology as LMPs'' since, ``in both cases, units are
dispatched on a least-cost basis that respects applicable transmission
constraints (i.e., congestion),'' and ``[t]he formula for price
calculation involves determination of the system marginal energy cost,
which is the cost of providing the next increment of energy to the
system, minus congestion costs, minus losses, and, in some cases, minus
the cost of carbon.'' \272\ As with LMP, these Western EIM price
components presumptively reflect the avoided cost of as-available
energy incurred by purchasing electric utilities that are able to
participate in the Western EIM region.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\272\ Xcel Comments at 7-8.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
178. We reject arguments that Western EIM prices should not be used
to establish as-available avoided cost energy rates for sales by QFs.
With respect to the unit commitment and dispatch scheduling cost
parameters ELCON refers to, it is true that the Western EIM is a real-
time imbalance market built on a decentralized unit commitment that may
not result in exactly the same real-time dispatch and LMP as would
result from an RTO market with centralized day-ahead unit commitment
and co-optimized energy and reserves. Nonetheless, Western EIM prices
represent quite precisely the avoided cost of as-available energy for
utilities operating in that market structure since those prices show
the cost of obtaining an additional unit of energy at any particular
place and time. With regard to the argument of Union of Concerned
Scientists concerning the cost recovery mechanisms available to
utility-owned and -affiliated generation,\273\ as discussed above with
respect to the rebuttable presumption that LMP may be used for avoided
cost rate determination, we do not find these unproven allegations of
use of retail cost recovery mechanisms to subsidize wholesale RTO/ISO
market participation at a loss sufficient to make a blanket finding
prohibiting the use of Western EIM prices to set as-available avoided
cost energy rates for sales by QFs.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\273\ Union of Concerned Scientists Comments at 9.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
179. With regard to the argument concerning the ability to
participate in the Western EIM raised by Solar Energy Industries,\274\
for PURPA rate purposes, it is not relevant whether QFs are able to
participate in the Western EIM. The rates at issue here are intended,
per the statute, to reflect the costs of alternative electric energy
that the purchasing utility is avoiding. In this context, all that
matters is whether the Western EIM's prices accurately reflect a
purchasing electric utility's avoided costs for energy. Thus, as long
as the purchasing electric utility is able to participate in the
Western EIM, a rebuttable presumption should apply that Western EIM
prices reflect the purchasing electric utility's avoided costs for
energy.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\274\ Solar Energy Industry Comments at 27.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
4. Use of Market Hub Prices as a Permissible Rate for Certain As-
Available QF Energy Sales
a. NOPR Proposal
180. In the NOPR, the Commission recognized that competitive
bilateral energy markets have arisen outside of the RTO/ISO energy
markets. Particularly in the Western United States, price hubs such as
the Mid-Columbia (Mid-C) and Palo Verde hubs are liquid markets with
prices the Commission has recognized as representing competitive market
prices at those hubs.\275\ For the same reasons that LMPs could
represent an appropriate avoided cost energy rate for QFs selling to
electric utilities located in RTO/ISO markets, the Commission proposed
to find that liquid market hubs can represent appropriate rates for QFs
selling to electric utilities located outside of RTO/ISO markets. Like
LMP, liquid market hubs would rely on competition to derive an avoided
cost. From a price determination perspective, liquid market hub prices
differ from LMP mainly in that they measure price at only one or a few
points, whereas RTOs/ISOs derive unique LMPs for all receipt and
delivery points on a specific area of the system.\276\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\275\ NOPR, 168 FERC ] 61,184 at P 52 (citing Price Discovery in
Nat. Gas and Elec. Mkts., 109 FERC ] 61,184, at P 66 (2004)
(approving the use of published prices at market hubs with
sufficient liquidity to set prices charged in tariffs); El Paso
Elec. Co., 148 FERC ] 61,051, at P 7 (2014) (approving the use of
the Palo Verde price to set imbalance charges); Idaho Power Co., 121
FERC ] 61,181 at P 27 (2007) (approving use of Mid-Columbia prices
to set energy imbalance charge); PacifiCorp, 95 FERC ] 61,467, at
62,676 (2001) (approving setting energy imbalance rate at average of
four market hub prices); Pinnacle West Energy Corp., 92 FERC ]
61,248, at 61,791 (2000) (accepting the use of the Palo Verde price
to set prices for affiliate transactions because the Palo Verde
Index is a recognized market hub with competitive prices)).
\276\ NOPR, 168 FERC ] 61,184 at P 53.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
181. Consequently, the Commission proposed in the NOPR to revise
the PURPA Regulations in 18 CFR 292.304 to add a subsection (b)(7)
which, in combination with new subsection (e)(1), would permit a state
to set the as-available energy rate paid to a QF by electric utilities
located outside of RTO/ISO markets at energy rates established at
liquid market hubs. The Commission proposed to define Market Hub Prices
as prices determined at a liquid market hub to which the purchasing
electric utility has reasonable access. States electing to set QF
energy rates using a Market Hub Price also would identify the
particular market hub used to set the
[[Page 54664]]
price. Such determination would require the state to find that the
prices at such hub are competitive prices that reflect the costs an
electric utility would avoid but for the purchase from the QF.\277\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\277\ Id. P 56.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
b. Comments
i. Comments in Support
182. Arizona Public Service and El Paso Electric state that the
Palo Verde/Hassayampa hub represents a regional liquid market hub that
could be used to set as-available energy avoided costs.\278\ Portland
General likewise asserts that the Mid-C price hub should be approved as
appropriate for use in establishing as-available energy avoided
costs.\279\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\278\ Arizona Public Service Comments at 6-8; El Paso Electric
Comments at 2-3.
\279\ Portland General Comments at 6-7.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
183. Xcel provides two additional factors to support the liquid
market hub proposal. First, Xcel cites to the 2018 State of the Market
report issued by the Commission's Office of Enforcement's Division of
Energy Market Oversight, which states that trading hub prices generally
align with energy prices associated with competitive, market-based
sales. Second, Xcel cites to wholesale power sales contracts providing
for the purchase of excess energy based on a combination of day-ahead
prices at Palo Verde and at Four Corners, which Xcel asserts
demonstrates that prices at Palo Verde and Four Corners are reasonably
representative of the value of energy.\280\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\280\ Xcel Comments at 8.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
ii. Comments in Opposition
184. Several commenters argue that liquid market hubs are short-
term spot markets and do not represent long-term energy rates or the
other costs associated with that energy including, but not limited to,
congestion, transmission, and capacity costs.\281\ Other commenters
express concern with setting QF prices at short-term liquid hub prices
while allowing utilities to rate base and recover their long-term
investments.\282\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\281\ IdaHydro Comments at 11; Southeast Public Interest
Organizations Comments at 19.
\282\ IdaHydro Comments at 11; Industrial Energy Consumers
Comments at 12-13.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
185. Public Interest Organizations assert that the liquid market
hub proposal is discriminatory because non-QF generators are not
limited to the liquid market hub price and utilities can, and regularly
do, pay effective prices for energy that exceed the price determined by
regional trading.\283\ Union of Concerned Scientists similarly asserts
that liquid market hub prices are distorted by the participation of
integrated utilities that submit bids below their total costs.\284\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\283\ Public Interest Organizations Comments at 64.
\284\ Union of Concerned Scientists Comments at 8.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
186. Industrial Energy Consumers oppose the liquid market hub
pricing proposal because such markets are not sufficiently competitive,
nondiscriminatory, and transparent to be used as the basis for
calculating a utility's avoided cost payment.\285\ Industrial Energy
Consumers urge the Commission not to assume that non-competitive
markets are, in fact, competitive.\286\ Southeast Public Interest
Organizations state that no southeast state could credibly identify a
particular market hub that is reasonably accessible and has competitive
prices that actually relate to the costs an electric utility would
avoid but for the purchase from the QF.\287\ Southeast Public Interest
Organizations also assert that the liquid market hub proposal does not
require states to determine whether liquid market hub prices represent
a utility's avoided costs, and therefore the proposal would allow
liquid market hubs to set avoided energy prices even when they do not
represent avoided energy costs.\288\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\285\ Industrial Energy Consumers Comments at 12.
\286\ Id.
\287\ Southeast Public Interest Organizations Comments at 18.
\288\ Id. at 19.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
187. ELCON asserts that a liquid regional hub does not necessarily
imply liquidity at a more granular level.\289\ According to ELCON, the
basis spread resulting from transmission congestion outside of RTO/ISOs
is often opaque in real time and poorly documented in hindsight, and
this is a clear indication that discriminatory treatment and barriers
to the bulk transmission system persist under current conditions
outside of RTO/ISOs.\290\ ELCON states that for these and other
reasons, bilateral markets alone are insufficient to serve as complete
avoided cost measures.\291\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\289\ ELCON Comments at 25.
\290\ Id.
\291\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
188. Allco states that prices at liquid market hubs would suffer
from shortcomings with respect to small QFs connected to the
distribution system, because purchases from such QFs also allow the
purchasing utility to avoid transmission costs, including line
losses.\292\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\292\ Allco Comments at 7-8.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
iii. Commission Determination
189. We adopt the proposal in the NOPR to give the states
flexibility to set as-available avoided cost energy rates using prices
from a liquid market hub to which the purchasing electric utility has
reasonable access. For the reasons explained in the NOPR, we find that
liquid market hubs can represent appropriate as-available avoided cost
energy rates for QFs selling to electric utilities located outside of
RTO/ISO markets. However, as the Commission also found in the NOPR,
before relying on prices from liquid market hubs, a state must find
that the liquid market hub price in question represents the purchasing
utility's avoided cost for as-available energy.\293\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\293\ See NOPR, 168 FERC ] 61,184 at PP 53, 56.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
190. Examples of factors a state reasonably could consider in
making this determination (in addition to the core finding that the
liquid market hub represents the purchasing utility's avoided cost for
as-available energy) are: (1) Whether the hub is sufficiently liquid
that prices at the hub represent a competitive price; \294\ (2) whether
the prices developed at the hub are sufficiently transparent; (3)
whether the electric utility has the ability to deliver power from such
hub to its load, even if its load is not directly connected to the hub;
and (4) whether the hub represents an appropriate market to derive an
energy price for the electric utility's purchases from the relevant QFs
given the electric utility's physical proximity to the hub. These
factors are not intended to be exhaustive, and states reasonably could
consider other factors in identifying a relevant liquid market hub for
setting as-available QF energy rates.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\294\ In considering whether a hub is sufficiently liquid,
states could, for example, consider such factors as those identified
by the Commission in Price Discovery in Nat. Gas and Elec. Mkts.,
109 FERC ] 61,184, at P 66.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
191. In order for prices at market hubs to represent a purchasing
electric utility's avoided costs, the market hub price may need to be
subject to adjustments to account for transmission costs the electric
utility would incur before such prices could serve as a factor in
determining appropriate QF rates.\295\ In addition, market prices in a
region may be determined based on a formula that includes adjustments
to the market hub price or that incorporates prices at more than one
market hub located in the region, when such prices represent standard
pricing practice in the region where the purchasing electric utility is
located.\296\ Such adjustments may be necessary to ensure that the
[[Page 54665]]
competitive market price reflects a purchasing utility's actual avoided
costs for as-available energy.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\295\ Other adjustments also may be necessary in other
situations in order for the adjusted hub price to reasonably reflect
the purchasing electric utility's avoided cost.
\296\ NOPR, 168 FERC ] 61,184 at P 58.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
192. Arguments regarding the short-term nature of liquid market
hubs and claims that use of such prices is discriminatory are addressed
in Section IV.B.2 above.
193. We will not address in this final rule arguments about whether
particular market hubs should be found to represent avoided costs or,
to the contrary, that particular market hubs may be too illiquid or
insufficiently granular, or that prices at particular market hubs may
not reflect avoided costs. We are not making any determination in this
final rule that the prices at any specific market hub do or do not
represent the avoided costs of any specific utility. Rather, we are
allowing the states the flexibility to rely on prices at liquid market
hubs to set as-available avoided cost energy rates for QF sales in
regions outside RTO/ISO markets upon a state finding that it is
appropriate to do so given the specific circumstances governing a
particular market hub and the purchasing utility involved. The
aggrieved entity would be able to challenge the state's decision to use
a liquid market hub price in the appropriate forum, which could include
any one or more of the following: (1) Initiating or participating in
proceedings before the relevant state commission or governing body; (2)
filing for judicial review of any state regulatory proceeding in state
court (under PURPA section 210(g)); or, alternatively (3) filing a
petition for enforcement against the state at the Commission and, if
the Commission declines to act, later filing a petition against the
state in U.S. district court (under PURPA section 210(h)(2)(B)).\297\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\297\ See Policy Statement Regarding the Commission's
Enforcement Role Under Section 210 of the Public Utility Regulatory
Policies Act of 1978, 23 FERC ] 61,304.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
194. With respect to Southeast Public Interest Organizations'
assertion that the liquid market hub proposal in the NOPR does not
require states to determine whether liquid market hub prices represent
a utility's avoided costs, the Commission intended to impose such a
requirement as a prerequisite before a liquid market hub may be relied
on as a measure of a purchasing utility's avoided cost of as-available
energy. However, we acknowledge that the regulatory text in the NOPR
was ambiguous in that regard. Therefore, the regulatory text of 18 CFR
292.304(b)(7)(i) in the final rule has been revised to make this more
clear.
c. Proposed Modifications
i. Comments
195. APPA requests that the Commission clarify that, in addition to
liquid market hubs, as-available energy avoided costs could be
determined based on prices of comparable competitive quality.\298\ APPA
states that amending the proposed regulation in this fashion would also
enable utilities proximate to (or embedded within) RTO/ISO markets to
reference prices in those markets as viable alternatives in
establishing avoided costs.\299\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\298\ APPA Comments at 13.
\299\ Id. at 13.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
196. The California Commission requests that the Commission clarify
that states previously were permitted to use liquid market hub prices
under the current PURPA Regulations and that the proposed revisions
simply codify and confirm the validity of this past practice.\300\ The
California Commission and Massachusetts DPU further request that the
proposed rules be modified to permit states to use competitive prices
to set both energy and capacity costs, and to not be limited to using
such mechanisms only for as-available energy prices.\301\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\300\ California Commission Comments at 24.
\301\ California Comments at 25; Massachusetts DPU Comments at
8-10.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
197. EEI notes that some states may be located in regions with
access to more than one market hub and those states should have the
flexibility to use an average of market hub prices or develop a formula
correlated to the appropriate market hubs to develop the electric
utility's avoided cost.\302\ EEI notes that this proposal is not new,
but its inclusion in the Commission's regulations will provide
certainty to states.\303\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\302\ EEI Comments at 26.
\303\ Id. at 27.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
198. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA assert that the liquid market hub
proposal should not be adopted without making significant changes.\304\
For example, they argue, only long-term contract prices reported at
market hubs should be used.\305\ Even with respect to market-hub prices
for long-term contracts, they assert that the Commission should include
safeguards to ensure that prices are set based on liquid trading with a
sufficient number of competitors to assure effective price discovery,
that prices are not subject to manipulation, and that reported price
indices are accurate and not subject to mis-reporting or other forms of
manipulation.\306\ Finally, they argue that the Commission should
require avoided costs to include the costs of transmission to and from
such hubs except in cases where the utility's system directly
interconnects with that hub.\307\ Resources for the Future makes
similar arguments.\308\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\304\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 60.
\305\ Id.
\306\ Id.
\307\ Id.
\308\ Resources for the Future Comments at 8.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
199. In contrast, NorthWestern asserts that liquid market hub
prices should be adjusted downward by a transmission differential to
reflect the cost of getting energy from the market to load.\309\
NorthWestern states that reliance on the market hub to establish
avoided costs only remains a valid option if the prices are less than
what it would cost a utility to build a resource to supply its
customers' needs.\310\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\309\ NorthWestern Comments at 5.
\310\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
ii. Commission Determination
200. We clarify that, in adopting a rule allowing states to use
liquid market hubs to determine as-available avoided energy costs, we
are not finding that the use of liquid market hubs for this purpose
prior to the issuance of this final rule was not permitted. Depending
on the specific circumstances, a state may appropriately have
determined, prior to the final rule, that a liquid market hub price
represented a purchasing utility's as-available avoided energy cost.
After the effective date of this final rule, an aggrieved entity may
seek review of a state's determination to use liquid market hubs in the
appropriate forum.\311\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\311\ See Policy Statement Regarding the Commission's
Enforcement Role Under Section 210 of the Public Utility Regulatory
Policies Act of 1978, 23 FERC ] 61,304.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
201. We confirm that: (1) States located in regions with access to
more than one market hub have the flexibility to use an appropriate
average of market hub prices or to develop an appropriate formula that
relies on data from relevant market hubs to develop an electric
utility's as-available avoided energy cost, so long as doing so yields
a price that accurately reflects the purchasing electric utility's as-
available avoided energy cost; \312\ (2) states must determine that a
liquid market hub is sufficiently liquid that its prices represent a
competitive price; \313\ and (3) the market hub price may need to be
subject to adjustments to account for transmission costs the electric
utility would incur.\314\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\312\ NOPR, 168 FERC ] 61,184 at P 58.
\313\ Id. P 57.
\314\ Id. P 58.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
[[Page 54666]]
202. Finally, we find that the general ruling requested by APPA
regarding the use of ``prices of comparable competitive quality'' to
set as-available avoided cost rates is beyond the scope of this
rulemaking in that here we were proposing only particular discrete
changes to our regulations for setting as-available avoided cost energy
rates charged by QFs.
5. Use of Formulas Based on Natural Gas Prices To Establish a
Permissible Rate for Certain As-Available QF Energy Sales
a. NOPR Proposal
203. The Commission observed in the NOPR that, in regions where
there are no RTOs/ISO or liquid market hubs, the price of electricity
generated by efficient combined-cycle natural gas generation facilities
would appear to represent a reasonable measure of a competitive energy
price.\315\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\315\ Id. P 59.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
204. The Commission therefore proposed to revise the PURPA
Regulations in 18 CFR 292.304 to add a subsection (b)(7) which, in
combination with new subsection (e)(1), would permit a state to set the
as-available energy rate paid to a QF by electric utilities located
outside of RTO/ISO markets at Combined Cycle Prices, defined as a
formula rate established by the state using published natural gas price
indices and a proxy heat rate for an efficient natural gas combined-
cycle generating facility. The state would need to determine that the
resulting Combined Cycle Price represents an appropriate approximation
of the purchasing electric utility's avoided costs. This determination
would involve consideration of such factors as, for example: (1)
Whether the cost of energy from an efficient natural gas combined-cycle
generating facility represents a reasonable approximation of a
competitive price in the purchasing electric utility's region; (2)
whether natural gas priced in accordance with a particular proposed
natural gas price index would be available in the relevant market; (3)
whether there should be an adjustment to the natural gas price to
appropriately reflect the cost of transporting natural gas to the
relevant market; and (4) whether the proxy heat rate used in the
formula should be updated regularly to reflect improvements in
generation technology. The Commission described the above factors as
not exhaustive and proposed providing states the flexibility to apply
other factors that also might be appropriate for consideration.\316\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\316\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
205. The Commission stated that natural gas price indices coupled
with the heat rate of an efficient natural gas combined-cycle
generating facility may be a reasonably accurate measure of avoided
cost, at least in those markets where natural gas-fired resources are
commonly the marginal units. In such markets, the Commission stated
that it would expect that new supplies of energy would need to be
offered at a price equal to or less than the incremental cost of using
these efficient gas units in order to displace them economically. Thus,
the Commission found preliminarily that using natural gas price indices
and the heat rate of an efficient combined-cycle natural gas generating
facility to establish an avoided cost energy rate relies on competitive
market forces, in this case competitive forces in natural gas markets
for the fuel used by natural gas combined-cycle generating facilities
that the purchasing electric utility, but for the purchase from the QF,
would generate itself or purchase from another source.\317\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\317\ Id. P 54.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
b. Comments
206. Several entities oppose the NOPR's Combined Cycle Prices
proposal.\318\ Allco asserts that this is exactly the type of
administrative avoided cost determination about which NARUC and
utilities have complained.\319\ Allco also argues that the only reason
for including the Combined Cycle Prices proposal in the Commission's
regulations is to create a menu of prices from which a state commission
or unregulated utility can choose the lowest price, which Allco claims
would not encourage QF generation, and would be inconsistent with the
rules of economic dispatch and the language of PURPA.\320\ Public
Interest Organizations argue that the Combined Cycle Price proposal is
discriminatory to QFs for all the same reasons that restricting QF
rates to LMP is discriminatory (i.e., because utilities can, and
allegedly do, pay effective prices for energy that exceed the
calculation from natural gas prices and assumed combined cycle heat
rates).\321\ Southeast Public Interest Organizations argue that the
Combined Cycle Prices proposal does not require states to include
variable O&M costs in the proxy combined cycle plant or an adjustment
for natural gas transportation, even though a utility-owned combined
cycle gas plant would be allowed to recover both types of costs.\322\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\318\ Allco Comments at 8; BluEarth Comments at 1-2; ELCON
Comments at 25-26; Industrial Energy Consumers Comments at 10-11;
Public Interest Organizations Comments at 64; R Street Comments at
5; Southeast Public Interest Organizations Comments at 19-20.
\319\ Allco Comments at 8.
\320\ Id.
\321\ Public Interest Organizations Comments at 64.
\322\ Southeast Public Interest Organizations Comments at 19-20.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
207. In contrast, R Street opposes the proposal because using
natural gas combined cycle plants as the basis for QF rates in non-RTO/
ISO regions could lead to the overpayment of a QF. R Street argues that
regions without organized wholesale markets should instead price QF
rates at the lowest cost resource based on an administratively
determined avoidable cost.\323\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\323\ R Street Comments at 5.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
208. Similarly, ELCON argues that the proposal is complicated by
the fact that natural gas units are not always marginal, especially in
export-constrained subregions when renewables output is high. ELCON
believes this proposal would be subject to extensive forecasting error,
and therefore argues that careful assessment should precede its
adoption.\324\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\324\ ELCON Comments at 26.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
209. Other entities support the NOPR's Combined Cycle Price
proposal.\325\ The California Commission and EEI argue that states
already had this flexibility under the current regulations, and request
that the Commission acknowledge this fact in a final rule.\326\
Similarly, other supporters of the Combined Cycle Price proposal argue
that states should have the ability to develop as-available energy
price formulas based on technologies other than combine cycle gas
plants, if doing so would more accurately reflect the relevant
purchasing utility's avoided cost.\327\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\325\ APPA Comments at 12-13; Arizona Public Service Comments at
6; California Commission Comments at 23; Chamber of Commerce
Comments at 4; Duke Energy Comments at 9-10; EEI Comments at 27; El
Paso Electric Comments at 3; Idaho Commission Comments at 3;
Southern Comments at 9.
\326\ California Commission Comments at 23; EEI Comments at 27-
28.
\327\ APPA Comments at 13; Duke Energy Comments at 10; EEI
Comments at 27; Idaho Commission Comments at 3; Southern Comments at
9-11.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
210. El Paso Electric argues that: (1) The gas index price should
be adjusted to account for the basis differential between the price at
the natural gas hub and the price of natural gas in or near the
utility's service area; and (2) states should be allowed to update the
formula periodically to reflect improved
[[Page 54667]]
efficiencies in combined cycle generating facilities.\328\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\328\ El Paso Electric Comments at 3-4.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
c. Commission Determination
211. We adopt the NOPR proposal to revise 18 CFR 292.304 to add a
subsection (b)(7) which, in combination with new subsection (e)(1),
would permit a state to set the as-available energy rate paid to a QF
by electric utilities located outside of RTO/ISO markets at Combined
Cycle Prices, defined as a formula rate established by the state using
published natural gas price indices and a proxy heat rate for an
efficient natural gas combined-cycle generating facility. We also
clarify that the formulas used to set as-available energy rates based
on natural gas prices should include recovery of variable O&M costs.
212. While some commenters oppose allowing states to use Combined
Cycle Prices (or other competitive prices) to set avoided energy cost
rates, states already had the flexibility to determine avoided costs in
this manner under the current regulations, as the California Commission
and EEI observe.\329\ If Combined Cycle Prices accurately represent a
particular purchasing utility's avoided energy costs, their use would
be consistent with the Commission's existing definition of avoided
costs as ``the incremental costs to an electric utility of electric
energy or capacity or both which, but for the purchase from the
qualifying facility or qualifying facilities, such utility would
generate itself or purchase from another source.'' \330\ Furthermore,
as noted above in section IV.B.2, the use of competitive market prices,
including Combined Cycle Prices, to set QF rates is explicitly subject
to the requirement that such prices are equal to the purchasing
utility's avoided energy costs. Therefore, this proposal merely
codifies more explicitly an option for determining avoided cost rates
that already existed, i.e., where a state determines that a Combined
Cycle Price is a measure of the purchasing electric utility's avoided
cost for as-available energy.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\329\ States could have used any of the competitive prices
adopted in this final rule to set avoided cost energy rates as long
as such prices met, to the extent practicable, the factors described
18 CFR 292.304(e).
\330\ See 18 CFR 292.101(b)(6).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
213. The concerns of R Street, ELCON, and others that Combined
Cycle Prices may not reflect a particular purchasing electric utility's
avoided cost are addressed by the requirement that the state would need
to determine that the Combined Cycle Price indeed represents the
purchasing electric utility's avoided cost for as-available energy.
214. While some commenters requested that we expand the proposed
regulation explicitly to include technologies other than combined cycle
natural gas generating facilities, we decline to do so for two reasons.
First, as already mentioned, the current regulations are already
flexible enough to accommodate states calculating avoided costs based
on the cost of the generating units or technology that accurately
reflects the relevant purchasing utility's avoided cost.\331\ Second,
this proposal focused specifically on combined cycle technology, as
opposed to other generating technologies, because combined cycle
generation makes up such a large portion of the nation's generation
fleet.\332\ This relative ubiquity, coupled with the fact that combined
cycle natural gas generation facilities are often the marginal units in
many regions, justifies an elevated profile in the PURPA Regulations
for combined cycle technology compared to other technologies. This
final rule does not foreclose other technologies from being used for
avoided cost determination, upon an appropriate finding by the state
that they accurately measure a purchasing electric utility's avoided
cost for as-available energy.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\331\ See 18 CFR 292.101(b)(6).
\332\ According to EIA data, the nameplate capacity of natural
gas-fired combined cycle generation technology, exceeds the
nameplate capacity of generation from any other fuel source. See
EIA, Electric Power Annual Table 4.7.A Net Summer Capacity of
Utility Scale Units by Technology and by State, 2018 and 2017
(Megawatts), https://www.eia.gov/electricity/annual/html/epa_04_07_a.html, and 4.7.C Net Summer Capacity of Utility Scale
Units Using Primarily Fossil Fuels and by State, 2018 and 2017
(Megawatts), https://www.eia.gov/electricity/annual/html/epa_04_07_c.html.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
215. Southeast Public Interest Organizations support their
opposition to Combined Cycle Prices in part by claiming that the
Commission did not specifically require states to include variable O&M
in the formula. We agree that variable O&M expenses are an appropriate
cost component of formula rates and should be included in any Combined
Cycle Price formulae in order to accurately reflect the relevant
purchasing electric utility's avoided costs.
216. With respect to the arguments of Southeast Public Interest
Organizations regarding natural gas transportation costs, the
regulation we adopt in this final rule, 18 CFR 292.304(b)(7)(ii)(C),
specifically requires that states consider whether there should be an
adjustment to the natural gas price to appropriately reflect the cost
of transporting natural gas to the relevant market. As to El Paso
Electric's arguments regarding index price adjustments using basis
differentials, and periodic formula updates to reflect efficiency
improvements, we note that the revisions to the PURPA Regulations,
which we adopt in this final rule, provide that states which choose to
rely on Combined Cycle Prices must consider, when designing their
formulae, whether and to what extent to include these costs, based on
their assessment of how best to identify a relevant purchasing electric
utility's avoided cost for as-available energy.\333\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\333\ See new 18 CFR 292.304(b)(7)(ii).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
6. Permitting the Energy Rate Component of a Contract To Be Fixed at
the Time of the LEO Using Forecasted Values of the Estimated Stream of
Market Revenues
217. The NOPR noted that, frequently, price forecasts are available
for LMPs in RTOs/ISOs, for liquid market hubs located outside of RTOs/
ISOs, and for natural gas pricing hubs. Accordingly, the NOPR suggested
that such forecasts could be used to allow QFs to request a fixed
energy rate component calculated at the time a LEO is incurred. The
Commission therefore proposed to add a new option in 18 CFR
292.304(d)(1)(iii) permitting fixed energy rates to be based on
forecasted estimates of the stream of revenue flows during the term of
the contract.\334\ In other words, states could rely on estimates of
forecasted energy prices at the time of delivery over the anticipated
life of the contract--such estimates are commonly referred to as
forward price curves--to develop a fixed energy rate component for that
contract when such estimates reflect the purchasing electric utility's
avoided costs.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\334\ NOPR, 168 FERC ] 61,184 at P 61.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
218. The NOPR stated that the fixed energy rate component of the
contract could be a single energy rate, based on the amortized present
value of the forecast energy prices, or it could be a series of
specified energy rates that are different in future years (or other
periods).\335\ Under this proposal, the QF would be able to establish,
at the time the LEO is incurred, the applicable energy rate(s) for the
entire term of a contract; however, the energy rate in the contract
could be different from year-to-
[[Page 54668]]
year (or some other period) and nevertheless comply with the current
requirement in 18 CFR 292.304(d)(2)(ii) that the energy rate be fixed
for the term of the contract.\336\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\335\ Id. P 62 (noting that the PURPA Regulations already
require that the fixed energy rate would need to account for the
operating characteristics of the QF, including the QF's ability to
deliver energy during peak periods and the utility's ability to
dispatch energy from the QF (citing 18 CFR 292.304(e)(2)).
\336\ Id. (noting that this is permissible under the
Commission's existing PURPA Regulations (citing Windham Solar LLC,
157 FERC ] 61,134, at PP 5-6 (2016) (Windham Solar) (``[A]lthough
state regulatory authorities cannot preclude a QF . . . from
obtaining a legally enforceable obligation with a forecasted avoided
cost rate, we remind the parties that the Commission's regulations
allow state regulatory authorities to consider a number of factors
in establishing an avoided cost rate. These factors which include,
among others, the availability of capacity, the QF's
dispatchability, the QF's reliability, and the value of the QF's
energy and capacity, allow state regulatory authorities to establish
lower avoided cost rates for purchases from intermittent QFs than
for purchases from firm QFs.'' (citing 18 CFR 292.304(e)-(f))
(footnote omitted))).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
a. Comments
219. Two commenters oppose the NOPR proposal to add a new option in
18 CFR 292.304(d)(1)(iii) permitting fixed energy rates to be based on
forecasted estimates of the stream of revenue flows during the life of
the contract.\337\ Southeast Public Interest Organizations and Mr.
Mattson state that the NOPR proposal is a departure from past
precedent.\338\ Southeast Public Interest Organizations state that this
proposal suffers the same deficiencies as the LMP and liquid market hub
price proposals. Furthermore, according to Southeast Public Interest
Organizations, the NOPR provides no analysis as to how or whether the
forward price curves result in just and reasonable and non-
discriminatory rates as required by PURPA.\339\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\337\ Southeast Public Interest Organizations Comments at 25;
Mr. Mattson Comments at 26.
\338\ Southeast Public Interest Organizations Comments at 25;
Mr. Mattson Comments at 26.
\339\ Southeast Public Interest Organizations Comments at 25.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
220. Other commenters support the NOPR proposal to add a new option
in 18 CFR 292.304(d)(1)(iii) permitting fixed energy rates to be based
on forecasted estimates of the stream of revenue flows during the term
of the contract.\340\ The South Dakota Commission and Pennsylvania
Commission state that they support the NOPR proposal on forecasted
values of the estimated stream of revenues because it forecasts a
steady stream of revenue and provides built-in flexibility.\341\
According to these commenters, the proposal also balances the QF's need
for a steady stream of revenue with the purchasing electric utility's
responsibility to have a prudent mix of supply contracts for its
provider of last resort obligations.\342\ The Chamber of Commerce
states that, while future rates are not guaranteed to materialize, the
projected rates will more accurately reflect those realized than a
single avoided cost rate set at the inception of a QF contract.\343\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\340\ Allco Comments at 8; APPA Comments at 14; Arizona Public
Service Comments at 2-3; Chamber of Commerce Comments at 4-5;
Connecticut Authority at 13; Distributed Sun Comments at 2; EEI
Comments at 28-30; Idaho Commission Comments at 4; NorthWestern
Comments at 6; NRECA Comments at 8; Pennsylvania Commission Comments
at 8; Resources for the Future Comments at 8; South Dakota
Commission Comments at 3.
\341\ Pennsylvania Commission Comments at 8-9; South Dakota
Commission Comments at 3.
\342\ Pennsylvania Commission Comments at 8-9.
\343\ Chamber of Commerce Comments at 4-5.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
221. Arizona Public Service states that it supports the proposal
because it grants states additional flexibility, which helps protect
utilities' customers from over-paying for generation due to QFs need
for sales guarantees and financing.\344\ NRECA agrees that states must
have flexibility in determining forecasted market prices including
appropriate discounting to ensure that utilities and consumers are not
locked into contracts with fixed prices that are higher than prevailing
market prices.\345\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\344\ Arizona Public Service Comments at 2-3.
\345\ NRECA Comments at 8.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
222. NRECA requests that the Commission clarify proposed revisions
to 18 CFR 292.304(d)(1)(i), (ii), and (iii) to state that an electric
utility is exempt from offering a stream of market revenue as payment,
even if there is a market hub price that could be relevant.\346\ The
Connecticut Authority also suggests that the Commission modify 18 CFR
292.304(d)(1)(ii) to specify that a state may set a series of energy
rates. For this option, Connecticut Authority argues, the regulatory
text should provide greater regulatory and commercial certainty to QF
developers, avoiding disputes with distribution utilities and
states.\347\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\346\ Id. at 9.
\347\ Connecticut Authority Comments at 14.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
223. Connecticut Authority supports revisions to 18 CFR
292.304(d)(2) because the rule would permit a state to limit a QF's
option to select a preferred energy rate methodology.\348\ Connecticut
Authority also supports the proposed 18 CFR 202.304(d)(iii) that
permits states to set a stated or fixed rate for energy that is
calculated using the present value of the expected stream of revenue
from as-available energy rates during the life of the contract or LEO.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\348\ Id. at 13.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
224. EEI states that this proposal is not novel, and as an example
notes that the Commission and a federal district court have already
found that the Connecticut Authority could set avoided cost rates based
on a forecast of future avoided costs.\349\ According to EEI, the
Commission has not ruled either that any form of forecasting is
mandated or that any is unacceptable.\350\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\349\ EEI Comments at 28 (citing Allco Renewable Energy Ltd. v.
Mass. Elec. Co., 208 F. Supp. 3d. 390, 395 (D. Mass. 2016); Windham
Solar, 157 FERC ] 61,134 at P 5.
\350\ EEI Comments at 28-30.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
225. Allco states that the proposed new option in 18 CFR
292.304(d)(1)(iii) permitting fixed energy rates to be based on
forecasted estimates of the stream of revenue flows during the life of
the contract is consistent with PURPA section 210 and is already
permitted. Allco also states that forecasts need to be non-
discriminatory. According to Allco, utilities and states frequently use
one forecast when dealing with QFs and another when obtaining approval
for their favored projects; Allco asserts that this practice is
discriminatory.\351\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\351\ Allco Comments at 8.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
226. APPA states that the proposed change is a logical extension of
the conclusion that market options are a legitimate alternative means
of specifying avoided costs.\352\ Distributed Sun states that it
supports permitting states to set fixed energy rates with forward
curves or through competitive solicitations.\353\ NorthWestern supports
the proposal to permit fixed energy rates to be on a forward price
curve developed from prices in either the organized markets or liquid
market hubs.\354\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\352\ APPA Comments at 14.
\353\ Distributed Sun Comments at 2.
\354\ NorthWestern Comments at 6.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
b. Commission Determination
227. We adopt the proposal to add a new option in 18 CFR
292.304(d)(1)(iii) permitting fixed energy rates to be based on
forecasted estimates of the stream of revenue flows during the term of
the contract. The Commission has previously permitted the use of this
method to establish energy and capacity rates over the term of a
contract or LEO.\355\ Nevertheless, given the flexibilities we adopt in
this final rule with respect to competitive market prices and variable
energy rates, we clarify here that a state may use competitive market
prices and/or variable energy rates in the context of a more fixed
estimated avoided cost energy rate (together with a fixed avoided
capacity rate) that is determined at the time an LEO or contract is
incurred. The fixed energy rate component of the contract could be
[[Page 54669]]
a single rate, based on the amortized present value of forecast energy
prices, or it could be a series of specified rates that change from
year-to-year (or other periods) in future years. We also will allow the
state to establish the applicable energy rate(s) for the QF for the
entire term or the rate may change from year-to-year (or some other
period) of the contract at the time the LEO is incurred.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\355\ Windham Solar, 157 FERC ] 61,134 at P 4 (citing 18 CFR
292.304(d)(2)).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
228. Southeast Public Interest Organizations and Mr. Mattson state
that the NOPR proposal is a departure from past precedent. The very
purpose of a proceeding like this is to consider changes to our
regulations and our doing so is not impermissible.
229. Southeast Public Interest Organizations also state that the
proposal suffers the same deficiencies as the LMP and liquid market hub
pricing proposals and that the NOPR provides no evidence as to how or
if the forward price curves present just and reasonable and non-
discriminatory rates as required by PURPA. Given that we find above
that LMPs and liquid market hub prices may reflect avoided as-available
energy costs and that estimates of such prices over the term of a
contract can therefore reflect a purchasing electric utility's avoided
as-available costs over time, we do not believe Southeast Public
Interest Organizations and Mr. Mattson's concerns are justified.
230. Although, as described below, we allow states to require
variable avoided cost energy rates, allowing forward price curves
determined at the time an LEO is incurred provides an additional option
for states to calculate avoided energy costs in advance while also
using transparent metrics for those calculations. Use of the forward
price curve does not deter the adoption of just and reasonable and non-
discriminatory rates required by PURPA, moreover, and insofar as we
require that states determine that the estimated stream of revenues
reflects the purchasing electric utility's avoided energy, such pricing
is fully consistent with the statute's requirements. With regard to
forecasts, we acknowledge that the forecast used to set the avoided
cost rate must meaningfully and reasonably reflect the utility's
avoided costs over time.\356\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\356\ See 18 CFR 292.304(b)(5). Rates calculated at the time of
a LEO (for example, a contract) do not violate the requirement that
the rates not exceed avoided costs if they differ from avoided costs
at the time of delivery.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
231. We decline to modify this proposal expressly either to permit
or prohibit a state from setting a series of estimated avoided energy
costs over time. Each state will be required to determine whether a
particular estimated stream of revenues represents a purchasing
electric utility's avoided costs over a specified term. Similarly, in
order to provide states flexibility to use LMPs and other competitive
market prices to establish as-available avoided energy costs, we will
not require a state to use this option to guarantee a stream of
revenues.
7. Providing for Variable Energy Rates in QF Contracts
a. Background
232. As explained above, if a QF chooses to sell energy and/or
capacity pursuant to a contract, the PURPA Regulations currently
provide the QF the option of receiving the purchasing electric
utility's avoided cost calculated and fixed at the time the LEO is
incurred.\357\ The Commission's justification in Order No. 69 for
allowing QFs to fix their rate at the time of the LEO for the entire
term of a contract was that fixing the rate provides certainty
necessary for the QF to obtain financing.\358\ The Commission stated
that its regulations pertaining to LEOs ``are intended to reconcile the
requirement that the rates for purchases equal the utilities' avoided
costs with the need for qualifying facilities to be able to enter
contractual commitments based, by necessity, on estimates of future
avoided costs.'' \359\ Further, the Commission agreed with the ``need
for certainty with regard to return on investment in new
technologies.'' \360\ The Commission stated its belief that any
overestimations or underestimations ``will balance out.'' \361\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\357\ 18 CFR 292.304(d)(2)(ii).
\358\ Order No. 69, FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 30,128 at 30,880
(justifying the rule on the basis of ``the need for certainty with
regard to return on investment in new technologies'').
\359\ Id.
\360\ Id.
\361\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
233. The provision that QFs be permitted to fix their rates for the
entire term of a contract or other LEO has proved to be one of the most
controversial aspects of the Commission's PURPA Regulations. Some
commenters at the Technical Conference submitted data indicating that
energy prices have declined in recent years, leaving the fixed energy
portion of the QF rate, even when levelized, well above market prices
that likely would represent the purchasing electric utility's actual
avoided energy costs at the time of delivery.\362\ Based on this
concern, some commenters recommended that the Commission allow states
to ``price generation [energy] from QFs at market prices, and to update
those prices regularly so that the prices for [QFs] are not burdensome
on customer rates'' and that the Commission should limit avoided cost
energy rates in a LEO to no higher than avoided cost rates at the time
of delivery.\363\ QFs, in turn, argued that elimination of the option
to fix QF rates for the term of a contract would threaten a QF's
ability to obtain financing.\364\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\362\ See Alliant Energy Comments, Docket No. AD16-16-000, at 5
(Nov. 7, 2016) (``Current market-based wind prices in the Iowa
region of MISO are approximately 25 [percent] lower than the PURPA
contract obligation prices [Interstate Power and Light Company] is
forced to pay for the same wind power for long-term contracts
entered into as of June 2016. As a result, PURPA-mandated wind power
purchases associated with just one project could cost Alliant
Energy's Iowa customers an incremental $17.54 million above market
wind prices over the next 10 years.'') (emphasis in original); EEI
Supplemental Comments, Docket No. AD16-16-000, attach. A at 3-4
(June 25, 2018) (EEI Supplemental Comments) (``On August 1, 2014, a
10-year fixed price contract at the Mid-Columbia wholesale power
market trading hub was priced at $45.87/MWh. On June 30, 2016, the
same contract was priced as $30.22/MWh, a decline of 34 [percent] in
less than two years. However, over the next 10 years, PacifiCorp has
a legal obligation to purchase 51.9 million MWhs under its PURPA
contract obligations at an average price of $59.87/MWh. The average
forward price curve for the Mid-Columbia trading hub during the same
period is $30.22/MWh, or 50 [percent] below the average PURPA
contract price that PacifiCorp will pay. The additional price
required under long-term fixed contracts will cost PacifiCorp's
customers $1.5 billion above current forward market prices over the
next 10 years.''); Comm'r Kristine Raper, Idaho Commission Comments,
Docket No. AD16-16-000, at 3-4 (filed June 30, 2016) (``Idaho Power
demonstrated that the average cost for PURPA power since 2001 has
exceed the Mid-Columbia (Mid-C) Index Price and is projected to
continue to exceed the Mid-C price through 2032. Likewise,
PacifiCorp's levelized avoided cost rates for 15-year contract terms
in Wyoming shows a decrease of approximately 50 [percent] from 2011
through 2015 (from approximately $60 per megawatt-hour to less than
$30 per megawatt-hour).'').
\363\ EEI Supplemental Comments, attach. A at 4; see also
Southern Company Comments, Docket No. AD16-16-000, at 7 (filed June
30, 2016) (``[T]he avoided energy cost payment to the QF should be
based on actual avoided energy cost at the time the QF delivers
energy.'').
\364\ See Technical Conference, Docket No. AD16-16-000, Tr.
26:22-25, 27:1-3 (June 29, 2016) (filed July 8, 2016) (Technical
Conference Tr.) (Solar Energy Industries) (``The Power Purchase
Agreement is the single most important contract of the development
and financing of an energy project that's not owned by a utility.
Without the long-term commitment to buy the output of that agreement
at a fixed price, there is no predictable stream of revenue. Without
a predictable stream of revenues, there is no financing. Without any
financing, there is no project.'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
b. NOPR Proposal
234. In the NOPR, the Commission proposed to revise 18 CFR
292.304(d) to permit a state to limit a QF's option to elect to fix at
the outset of a LEO the energy rate for the entire length of its
contract or LEO, and instead allow the state the flexibility to require
QF energy
[[Page 54670]]
rates to vary during the term of the contract. However, under the
proposed revisions to 18 CFR 292.304(d), a QF would continue to be
entitled to a contract with avoided capacity costs calculated and fixed
at the time the contract or LEO is incurred. Only the energy rate in
the contract or LEO could be required by a state to vary. Further, the
NOPR did not propose to obligate states to require variable avoided
cost energy rates--they would retain the ability to allow the QF's
energy rate be fixed at the time the LEO is incurred.\365\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\365\ NOPR, 168 FERC ] 61,184 at P 67.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
235. The Commission preliminarily found compelling the record
evidence that overestimations have not been adequately balanced by
underestimations in past years. Further, it appeared to the Commission
that this trend may persist into the future with the continuing general
decline in the cost of both wind and solar generation.\366\
Consequently, the Commission found that it may be necessary to allow
states to provide for a variable energy rate in order to reflect more
accurately the purchasing electric utility's avoided costs and
therefore to satisfy the statutory requirement that QF rates not exceed
the utility's avoided cost and ``be just and reasonable to the electric
consumers of the electric utility and in the public interest.'' \367\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\366\ Id. P 68 (citing EIA, Today in Energy, Average U.S.
construction costs for solar and wind continued to fall in 2016
(Aug. 8, 2018), https://www.eia.gov/todayinenergy/detail.php?id=36813 (``Based on 2016 EIA data for newly constructed
utility-scale electric generators (those with a capacity greater
than one megawatt) in the United States, annual capacity-weighted
average construction costs for solar photovoltaic systems and
onshore wind turbines declined . . . .'')).
\367\ Id. P 68 (internal quotations omitted) (citing 16 U.S.C.
824a-3(b)(1)).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
236. The Commission acknowledged that the current PURPA Regulations
allowing a QF to fix its rates for the life of a contract or LEO were
based on the recognition that fixed rates are beneficial for obtaining
financing for QF projects. The Commission also recognized that QF
developers have continued to assert that they require fixed rates to
finance new projects. However, the Commission stated that it did not
view the proposed modification to the PURPA Regulations as materially
affecting the ability of QFs to obtain financing for several
reasons.\368\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\368\ Id. P 69.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
237. First, the Commission expressed its understanding that fixed
energy rates are not generally required in the electric industry in
order for electric generation facilities to be financed. For example,
RTO/ISO capacity markets provide only for fixed capacity payments,
leaving capacity owners to sell their energy into the organized
electric markets at LMPs that vary based on market conditions at the
time the energy is delivered. The Commission stated that these fixed
capacity and variable energy payments have been sufficient to permit
the financing of significant amounts of new capacity in the RTOs and
ISOs.\369\ Testimony presented at the Technical Conference similarly
showed that non-QF independent power projects located outside of RTOs
enter into contracts with fixed capacity and variable energy
prices.\370\ Other comments at the Technical Conference suggested that
a fixed capacity charge likewise would be adequate for financing a QF
project.\371\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\369\ Id. P 70 (citing Monitoring Analytics, LLC., Third
Quarter, 2018 State of the Market Report for PJM, January through
September, at 249, Table 5-6 (Nov. 8, 2018), https://www.monitoringanalytics.com/reports/PJM_State_of_the_Market/2018/2018q3-som-pjm.pdf (over 23,000 MW of new capacity constructed in
PJM Interconnection, L.L.C. since 2007-2008; including over 16,000
MW of new capacity added in the last four years)).
\370\ Id. (citing Technical Conference Tr. at 167-69 (Southern
Company) (``So if we enter into a bilateral contract with an
independent power producer for combustion turbine or combined cycle
capacity, we don't fix the energy price. The capacity payment is a
fixed payment. That's their fixed [stream]. The energy price is
typically indexed to the price of natural gas.''); id. at 178
(American Forest & Paper Association) (``Now, you sign a long-term
IPP contract. That contract [has] got a variable energy cost in
it.'')).
\371\ Id. P 70 (citing Solar Energy Industries Comments, Docket
No. AD16-16-000, at 3 (filed June 30, 2016) (``Developers need rates
for such sales of energy and/or capacity to be fixed.'') (emphasis
added)).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
238. The Commission further noted that there are financial products
available, such as contracts for differences, which allow generation
owners to hedge their exposure to fluctuating energy prices.\372\ The
Commission stated that financial products can provide additional
comfort to lenders regarding the level of energy rate revenues that a
QF can expect from the energy it delivers, in addition to the fixed
capacity payments the QF is entitled to receive under its
contract.\373\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\372\ Id. P 72 (citing Elec. Storage Participation in Mrkts.
Operated by Reg'l Transmission Org. and Independent Sys. Operators,
Order No. 841, 162 FERC ] 61,127, at P 299 (2018) (noting that
``market participants that purchase energy from the RTO/ISO markets
. . . may enter into bilateral financial transactions to hedge the
purchase of that energy'')).
\373\ Id. P 72.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
239. The Commission also explained that, although it may have been
true at the time the Commission promulgated its PURPA Regulations in
1980 that QFs needed to fix their energy rate for the term of their
contract in order to obtain financing of their facilities, there is
evidence that this no longer is true. This evidence comes in the form
of data, described below, showing that independent generators that have
not qualified as QFs under PURPA (including renewable resources that
could qualify as QFs but have not sought QF status) have been able to
obtain financing for new facilities. The Commission stated that the
fact that owners of such facilities, which do not have recourse to the
avoided cost rate provisions of PURPA, have been able to obtain
financing for new projects is relevant to the question of whether the
existing PURPA avoided cost provisions--including the requirement to
enter into contracts with fixed energy rates--are necessary for QFs to
obtain financing.\374\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\374\ Id. P 73.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
240. For example, EIA data showed that, since 2005, QFs have made
up only 10% to 20% of all renewable resource capacity in service in the
United States, demonstrating that most renewable resources no longer
need to rely on PURPA avoided cost rates to sell their output
economically.\375\ EIA data also showed that net generation of energy
by non-utility owned renewable resources in the United States escalated
from 51.7 terawatt hours (TWh) in 2005 when EPAct 2005 was passed, to
340 TWh in 2018. The Commission further observed that, while much of
this growth was in states located in RTOs/ISOs, there also was
significant growth of non-utility renewable generation in other states.
For example, net generation by non-utility renewable resources in the
region defined by EIA as the Mountain State region \376\ increased from
3.6 TWh in 2005 to 19.5 TWh in 2012, and to 42.5 TWh in 2018. Pacific
Northwest (Oregon and Washington) net non-utility generation from
renewable resources increased from 1.5 TWh in 2005, to 8.7 TWh in 2012,
and to 10.6 TWh in 2018.\377\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\375\ Id. P 74 (citing EIA, Today in Energy, North Carolina has
More PURPA-Qualifying Solar Facilities than any other State, figure
titled PURPA qualifying facilities (1980-2015) percent of total
renewable capacity (Aug. 23, 2016), https://eia.gov/todayinenergy/detail.php?id=27632).
\376\ Arizona, Colorado, Idaho, Montana, Nevada, New Mexico,
Utah, and Wyoming.
\377\ NOPR, 168 FERC ] 61,184 at P 74.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
241. The Commission found that EIA data on independently-owned
natural gas-fired generation capacity told a similar story. Natural
gas-fired capacity without the requisite cogeneration technology cannot
qualify as qualifying small power production or cogeneration, and thus
most of this capacity would not be within the scope of the PURPA
avoided cost rate provisions. The Commission cited to EIA data showing
that, in 2018,
[[Page 54671]]
approximately 44% of all energy produced by natural gas-fired
generation in the United States was generated by independently-owned
capacity.\378\ The total amount of energy produced in 2018 by
independently-owned natural gas-fired generation was 651 TWh, an
increase of 13.7% from 2017.\379\ Again, the percentage of
independently-owned natural gas generation outside of RTOs/ISOs was
lower than in RTOs/ISOs, but still was significant. In the Mountain
State region, 21.4% of the energy produced by natural gas-fired
generation in 2018 was produced by independently-owned capacity, and in
Oregon and Washington 45.4% of natural gas-fired energy was produced by
independently-owned capacity.\380\ From this, the Commission concluded
that independent owners of non-QF generation have been, and continue to
be, able to obtain financing for their facilities.\381\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\378\ NOPR, 168 FERC ] 61,184 at P 75 (citing EIA, Electric
Power Monthly with Data for December 2018, at tbl. 1.7.B, https://www.eia.gov/electricity/monthly/current_month/epm.pdf.).
\379\ Id.
\380\ Id.
\381\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
242. The Commission did not suggest that this evidence supports the
conclusion that substantial non-QF capacity is being financed and
constructed without any form of fixed revenue to support financing.
Rather, the Commission concluded that the evidence demonstrated that
the existing PURPA avoided cost rate provisions are not necessary for
some independent power generators to put in place contractual
arrangements, including fixed revenue streams, that are sufficient to
obtain financing. The Commission reasoned that QFs, which have the
ability to take advantage of PURPA's mandatory purchase requirements,
should be better positioned than non-QFs to negotiate the necessary
contractual arrangements for financing. Moreover, the Commission noted
that QFs are equally as well positioned as non-QF independent
generators to take advantage of federal and state incentives designed
to encourage the construction of renewable resources. \382\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\382\ Id. P 76.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
243. Further, the Commission pointed to evidence that the desire to
limit the effect of fixed QF contract rates had directly led to PURPA
implementation issues that affected QF financing in other respects,
particularly with respect to the length of QF contracts.\383\ For
example, a commissioner of the Idaho Commission testified at the
Technical Conference that the Idaho Commission's decision to limit QF
contracts to a two-year term was based on the Idaho Commission's
concern that longer contract terms at fixed rates would lead to
payments above avoided costs.\384\ Similarly, Southern Company
testified that the fixed rate requirement is ``resulting in . . .
typically shorter contract term lengths.'' \385\ Golden Spread Electric
Cooperative recommended that, if the fixed rate requirement is not
eliminated, the Commission permit shorter contract terms, ``as short as
one-year or three years at most.'' \386\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\383\ Id. P 65 (citing Natural Resources Defense Council
Comments, Docket No. AD16-16-000, at 4 (filed June 30, 2016)).
\384\ Id. P 65 (citing Technical Conference Tr. at 142-43 (Idaho
Commission) (``No matter the starting point, allowing QFs to fix
their avoided cost rates for long terms results in rates which will
eventually exceed and overestimate avoided cost rates into the
future. The longer the term, the greater the disparity. . . . [The
Idaho Commission] recently reduced PURPA contract lengths to two
years in order to correct the disparity. We didn't reduce contract
lengths to kill PURPA. We did it to allow periodic adjustment of
avoided cost rates.'')).
\385\ Id. P 65 (citing Technical Conference Tr. at 202 (Southern
Company)).
\386\ Id. P 65 (citing Golden Spread Electric Cooperative
Comments, Docket No. AD16-16-000, at 10 (filed June 30, 2016)).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
244. Finally, the Commission addressed one particular standard form
of QF contract rate currently employed by a number of utilities, which
is a one-part rate, applicable to each MWh of energy delivered by the
QF. This one-part rate is calculated to reflect both avoided capacity
costs and avoided energy costs. Contracts employing such rates also
typically impose a must purchase obligation on the purchasing utility.
The Commission stated that its proposed rule was not intended to
prevent states from implementing such an approach to setting QF
contract rates in the future. The Commission proposed that, to the
extent a state determines to establish a one-part QF contract rate that
recovers both avoided capacity and avoided energy costs, the rate must
continue to be subject to the QF's option to select a fixed rate for
the term of the contract, as provided in 18 CFR 304(d)(2)(ii). Any
requirement to impose a variable energy QF contract rate would need to
be accomplished through a multi-part rate that includes separate
avoided capacity cost rates and avoided energy cost rates.\387\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\387\ Id. P 81.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
c. General Comments on the NOPR Proposal
i. Comments in Support of NOPR Proposal
245. Several commenters support the NOPR proposal to allow energy
rates to vary in QF contracts and other LEOs, arguing it will reduce
overpayments and protect customers.\388\ In that regard, Duke Energy
asserts that the primary factor behind overpayment has been the
requirement to offer fixed avoided cost energy rates during a period of
rapidly declining energy prices.\389\ Several other commenters
similarly cite to the general decline of energy prices coupled with the
fact that QFs have been able to lock in rates over the life of a
contract or other LEO as reasons for their support of the NOPR
proposal.\390\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\388\ Conservative Action Comments at 1; Consumer Energy
Alliance Comments at 2; EEI Comments at 30-31; Idaho Power Comments
at 7-8; Idaho Commission Comments at 4; LG&E/KU Comments at 3;
NextEra Comments at 5; see also Alaska Power Comments at 1; Arizona
Public Service Comments at 3-4; Basin Comments at 6-8; Chamber of
Commerce Comments at 4; Freedom Center Comments at 1-2; R Street
Comments at 5; Tax Reform Comments at 1-2.
\389\ Duke Energy Comments at 5-7.
\390\ Consumer Energy Alliance Comments at 2; Idaho Power
Comments at 7-8; Idaho Commission Comments at 4; LG&E/KU Comments at
3; Ohio Commission Energy Advocate Comments at 4.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
246. Several commenters also support the NOPR's variable rate
proposal because it will allow states greater flexibility to determine
avoided cost rates accurately and to meet PURPA's consumer protection
goals.\391\ LG&E/KU states that such flexibility is appropriate and
necessary to meet the statutory requirement that ratepayers not pay a
rate that exceeds the electric utility's incremental cost of
alternative energy.\392\ NorthWestern argues that providing such
flexibility will assist in guaranteeing that customers are held
harmless by purchases of QF power.\393\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\391\ Alliant Energy Comments at 9; Duke Energy Comments at 8-9;
LG&E/KU Comments at 4; MA DPU Comments at 1, 7; NorthWestern
Comments at 6-7.
\392\ LG&E/KU Comments at 4.
\393\ NorthWestern Comments at 6-7.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
247. Supporters of the NOPR variable rate proposal also commented
on specific aspects of the proposal. These comments are discussed in
more detail in the following sections.
ii. Comments in Opposition to NOPR Proposal
248. Several commenters oppose the NOPR variable energy rate
proposal.\394\
[[Page 54672]]
In addition to objections as to specific aspects of that proposal,
which are discussed in the following sections, some commenters raise
threshold issues regarding this proposal.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\394\ Allco Comments at 9-11; AllEarth Comments at 2; Biogas
Comments at 2; BluEarth Comments at 2; CARE Comments at 3-5;
Biological Diversity Comments at 8; ELCON Comments at 18, 21-23;
EPSA Comments at 6-13; Massachusetts AG Comments at 8-9; North
Carolina DOJ Comments at 2-6; North Carolina Commission Staff
Comments at 2-4; New England Hydro Comments at 8; NIPPC, CREA, REC,
and OSEIA Comments at 29-48; North American-Central Comments at 4-6;
Public Interest Organizations Comments at 6-7, 27-51; Resources for
the Future Comments at 4-7; Solar Energy Industries Comments at 28-
38; SC Solar Alliance Comments at 4-10; Southeast Public Interest
Organizations Comments at 9-18; sPower Comments at 10-13; State
Entities Comments at 2-3; Mr. Mattson Comments at 26-27; Two Dot
Wind Comments at 11-13; Western Resource Councils Comments at 2.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
249. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA cite to the PURPA Conference
Report as expressing Congress's intent that QFs be entitled to long-
term fixed energy rates. Specifically, they cite to the statement in
the Conference Report that ``the Commission and States should look to
the reliability of that power to the utility and the cost savings to
the utility which may result at some later date by reason of supply to
the utility at that time of power from the cogenerator or small power
producer.'' \395\ According to NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA, this
statement shows that ``Congress also recognized that attempts to set
the rates based on the avoided costs at the time of delivery would
likely be insufficient to encourage such facilities.'' \396\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\395\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 27 (quoting Conf.
Rep. at 98-99).
\396\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
250. Harvard Electricity Law asserts that the Commission may not
authorize state regulators to change rates in existing contracts.\397\
Harvard Electricity Law then asserts that the Commission: (1) Attempts
to portray its agenda as consistent with Congressional intent by
providing a skewed summary of the legislative history; (2) presents an
unsupported statement that its rules will ``continue to encourage'' QF
development, which ignores the administrative record and fails to
account for regulatory changes since PURPA's enactment; (3) misreads
its own rules in claiming that repeal is necessary to protect
consumers; and (4) relies on a finding that fixed price energy
contracts are not necessary to encourage QFs that is based on
irrelevant data and questionable assumptions that are not grounded in
reasoned decision making.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\397\ Harvard Electricity Law Comments at 23 (citing API, 461
U.S. at 414).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
251. Harvard Electricity Law also asserts that allowing long-term
contracts to include variable rates is contrary to PURPA.\398\ In
support of this assertion, Harvard Electricity Law cites to two
decisions which it claims stand for the proposition that the
Commission's proposed rule would impose forbidden utility-type
regulation on QFs.\399\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\398\ Id. at 28.
\399\ Id. at 29 (citing Freehold Cogeneration Assoc. v. Bd. of
Regulatory Comm'rs. of N.J., 44 F.3d 1178, 1193 (3d Cir. 1995)
(Freehold Cogeneration); Smith Cogeneration Mgt. v. Corp. Comm'n.,
863 P.2d 1227 (Okla. 1993) (Smith Cogeneration)).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
252. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA and Public Interest Organizations
assert that it is unclear whether independent power producers that have
obtained financing did so with short-term variable rate
conditions.\400\ North American-Central argues that, if a variable rate
will preclude a QF from receiving financing in the first place, it is
irrelevant that a state might be more willing to offer a longer-term
contract.\401\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\400\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 46.
\401\ North American-Central Comments at 5-6.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
iii. Commission Determination
253. In this final rule, we adopt without modification the NOPR
variable rate proposal. We find that setting QF energy avoided cost
contract and other LEO rates at the level of the purchasing utility's
avoided energy costs at the time the energy is delivered is consistent
with PURPA, which limits QF rates to the purchasing utility's avoided
costs. Indeed, a variable energy avoided cost approach is a more
accurate way to ensure that payments to QFs equal, but do not exceed,
avoided costs.\402\ It is inevitable that, in contrast, over the life
of a QF contract or other LEO a fixed energy avoided cost rate, such as
that used in past years, will deviate from actual avoided costs.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\402\ 16 U.S.C. 824a-3(b)(1).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
254. As described in more detail in the following sections, the
record overwhelmingly supports our conclusions that long-term forecasts
of avoided energy costs are inherently less accurate, and that states
should be given the flexibility to rely on a more accurate variable
avoided cost energy rate approach. Further, there are numerous
instances where overestimates and underestimates have not balanced
out.\403\ When that has occurred, consumers have borne the brunt of the
overpayments, which subsidized QFs, in contravention of Congressional
intent and the Commission's expectations.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\403\ See Duke Comments at 6 (Duke's QF contracts cost $4.66
billion but its ``actual current avoided costs'' are $2.4 billion);
Idaho Power Comments at 10-11 (``The cost of PURPA generation
contained in Idaho Power's base rates, on a dollars per MWh basis,
is not just greater than Mid-C market prices, it is greater than all
the net power supply cost components currently recovered in base
rates. Idaho Power's average cost of PURPA generation included in
base rates is $62.49/MWh. At $62.49/MWh, the average cost of PURPA
purchases is greater than the average cost of FERC Account 501, Coal
at $22.79/MWh; greater than FERC Account 547, Natural Gas at $33.57/
MWh; greater than FERC Account 555, Non-PURPA Purchases at $50.64/
MWh; and significantly greater than what is being sold back to the
market as FERC Account 447, Surplus Sales at $22.41/MWh.'');
Portland General Comments at 5 (``for a typical 3 MW Solar QF
project that incurred a LEO in 2016 and reaches commercial
operations three years later, [Portland General's] customers would
pay 67% more for the project's energy than if the 2019 avoided cost
rate had been used. As a result of this lag, [Portland General's]
customers would pay an additional $1.6 million more for the energy
from the QF facility over the 15-year contract term.''); see also
NOPR, 168 FERC 61,184 at P 64 n.101 (citing Alliant Energy,
Comments, Docket No. AD16-16-000, at 5 (filed Nov. 7, 2016)
(``Current market-based wind prices in the Iowa region of MISO are
approximately 25% lower than the PURPA contract obligation prices
[Interstate Power and Light Company] is forced to pay for the same
wind power for long-term contracts entered into as of June 2016. As
a result, PURPA-mandated wind power purchases associated with just
one project could cost Alliant Energy's Iowa customers an
incremental $17.54 million above market wind prices over the next 10
years.'') (emphasis in original); EEI Supplemental, Comments,
attach. A at 3-4 (``On August 1, 2014, a 10-year fixed price
contract at the Mid-Columbia wholesale power market trading hub was
priced at $45.87/MWh. On June 30, 2016, the same contract was priced
as $30.22/MWh, a decline of 34% in less than two years. However,
over the next 10 years, PacifiCorp has a legal obligation to
purchase 51.9 million MWhs under its PURPA contract obligations at
an average price of $59.87/MWh. The average forward price curve for
the Mid-Columbia trading hub during the same period is $30.22/MWh,
or 50% below the average PURPA contract price that PacifiCorp will
pay. The additional price required under long-term fixed contracts
will cost PacifiCorp's customers $1.5 billion above current forward
market prices over the next 10 years.''); Comm'r Kristine Raper,
Idaho Commission Comments, Docket No. AD16-16-000, at 3-4 (filed
June 30, 2016) (``Idaho Power demonstrated that the average cost for
PURPA power since 2001 has exceed the Mid-Columbia (Mid-C) Index
Price and is projected to continue to exceed the Mid-C price through
2032. Likewise, PacifiCorp's levelized avoided cost rates for 15-
year contract terms in Wyoming shows a decrease of approximately 50%
from 2011 through 2015 (from approximately $60 per megawatt-hour to
less than $30 per megawatt-hour).'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
255. Given that PURPA section 210(b) prohibits the Commission from
requiring QF rates in excess of avoided costs,\404\ this record
evidence supports our decision to give the states the flexibility to
require variable avoided cost energy rates in QF contracts and other
LEOs to prevent QF rates from exceeding avoided costs. We discuss
specific aspects of the variable energy rate provisions below, but at
the outset address certain threshold issues raised in the comments.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\404\ This prohibition is described in Section IV.A.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
256. We reiterate the points made in detail above in Section II.
The variable energy avoided cost rate provision is not based on any
determination that the Commission's rules no longer should encourage QF
development. The question of whether QFs should continue to be
encouraged is a question for Congress. Rather, we are revising the
PURPA Regulations by giving states the flexibility to require variable
avoided cost energy rates in QF contracts and other LEOs in order to
better comply
[[Page 54673]]
with Congress's clear instruction in PURPA that the Commission may not
require QF rates in excess of a purchasing utility's avoided costs.
257. By its very nature, the question of fixed versus variable
energy rates is a question of how risk from increases in avoided energy
costs over the life of a QF contract or other LEO should be allocated.
Answering this question requires the Commission to allocate this risk
either to (i) customers of electric utilities, or (ii) QFs and their
investors and lenders. But the Commission does not have unlimited
discretion in how it resolves the question. Congress in PURPA section
210(b) provided guidance to the Commission in how it should perform
that allocation--by mandating that the Commission cannot adopt a rule
that provides for a rate that exceeds the incremental cost of
alternative electric energy.\405\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\405\ 16 U.S.C. 824a-3(b); see also 16 U.S.C. 824a-3(d); 18 CFR
292.101(b)(6), 292.304(b)(2).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
258. Opponents of variable avoided cost energy rates urge the
Commission to continue placing this risk on the customers of electric
utilities, as it did in the past, by retaining the option for QFs to
fix their avoided cost energy rates in their contracts or LEOs
notwithstanding record evidence, discussed elsewhere in this final
rule, that fixed energy rates compared to actual avoided costs have not
balanced out over time. But, after consideration of the record, the
Commission has decided instead to allow states to reduce the risk to
customers by giving states the flexibility to require variable avoided
cost energy rates in QF contracts and LEOs. The Commission's
determination ensures that the PURPA Regulations continue to be
consistent with the statutory avoided cost rate cap in PURPA section
210(b), coupled with the directive in the Conference Report that
customers of utilities not be required to subsidize QFs.\406\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\406\ Conf. Rep. at 98 (``The provisions of this section are not
intended to require the rate payers of a utility to subsidize
cogenerators or small power produc[er]s.'') (emphasis added).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
259. Third, there is no merit to the contention that the PURPA
Conference Report expresses Congressional intent that QFs are entitled
to long-term fixed energy rates. The statement in the Conference Report
cited by NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA does not support this
contention.\407\ The example provided in the PURPA Conference Report
was of a utility owning a hydroelectric generating facility. Congress
hypothesized that this utility might be able to avoid drawing down its
reservoir as a result of a purchase from a QF, and thereby be able to
generate electricity from the hydroelectric facility at a later date
rather than running a more expensive fossil fuel unit at that later
date. Congress stated that the avoided cost in its example should be
based on the cost of the more expensive fossil unit whose operation was
avoided at a later date rather than the avoided cost at the time the QF
delivered its energy.\408\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\407\ See NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 27 (quoting
Conf. Rep. at 98-99).
\408\ Id. at 98-99 (``In interpreting the term `incremental cost
of alternative energy,' the conferees expect that the Commission and
the states may look beyond the cost of alternative sources which are
instantaneously available to the utility. Rather, the Commission and
states should look to the reliability of that power to the utility
and the cost savings to the utility which may result at some later
date by reason of supply to the utility at that time of power from
the cogenerator or small power producer; for example an electric
utility which owns a source of hydroelectric power and which is
offered the sale of electric energy from a cogenerator or small
power producer might, if measured over the short term, have a low
incremental cost of alternative power because of its access to
hydropower; however, it may be the case that by purchasing from the
cogenerator or small power producer and saving hydropower for later
use, the utility can avoided the use of expensive electric energy
generated by fossil fired units during later months of its seasonal
generation cycle. Thus, viewed over the longer period of time, the
incremental cost of alternative electric energy might be
substantially higher than that measured by the instantaneously
available hydropower.'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
260. While Congress recognized that the better measure of avoided
cost in that scenario might be the cost of the alternative fossil fuel
unit that would not be run at that later date,\409\ nothing in the
quoted section of the PURPA Conference Report suggests that Congress
intended the Commission to require that all avoided cost energy rates
be fixed at the outset for the life of a QF contract or other LEO. And
nothing in the revision being implemented in this final rule would
prohibit a state from calculating a QF's avoided cost energy rate for a
QF contract or LEO in the manner suggested in the PURPA Conference
Report or, indeed, in the manner the Commission has long allowed, if a
state determined that such an approach best reflects the purchasing
electric utility's avoided costs.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\409\ Under the approach adopted in this final rule, with the
flexibility granted to states to adopt--but not a mandate directing
states to adopt--variable avoided cost energy rates for QF contracts
and other LEOs, states can adopt a pricing approach that best fits
their circumstances, including adopting the pricing approach
described by the Conference Report to address the circumstances
described by the Conference Report.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
261. Fourth, the variable avoided cost energy rate provision
adopted herein does not run afoul of the Freehold Cogeneration and
Smith Cogeneration cases cited by Harvard Electricity Law.\410\ Those
decisions, which overturned state avoided cost determinations allowing
for changes in QF rates, were based on the provision in the original
PURPA Regulations giving QFs the option to select contracts with long-
term fixed avoided cost rates.\411\ Indeed, the Smith Cogeneration
decision quotes at length from the explanation in Order No. 69 of the
Commission's justification for its requiring in its regulations fixed
avoided cost rates in QF contracts and LEOs.\412\ Neither decision
suggests that PURPA would prevent the Commission from revising its
regulations to allow states the flexibility to require variable avoided
cost energy rates, as the Commission is doing here.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\410\ Harvard Electricity Law Comments at 29 (citing Freehold
Cogeneration, 44 F.3d at 1193; Smith Cogeneration, 863 P.2d at
1227).
\411\ See Smith Cogeneration, 863 P.2d at 1241 (holding that
allowing reconsideration of established avoided costs ``makes it
impossible to comply with PURPA and FERC regulations requiring
established rate certainty for the duration of long term contracts
for qualifying facilities that have incurred an obligation to
deliver power'') (emphasis added); Freehold Cogeneration, 44 F.3d at
1193 (relying on Smith Cogeneration analysis that ``that PURPA and
FERC regulations preempted the State Commission rule'') (emphasis
added).
\412\ Smith Cogeneration, 863 P.2d at 1240.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
262. Harvard Electricity Law also relies on Freehold Cogeneration
and Smith Cogeneration to assert that the Commission is imposing
``utility-type'' regulation in violation of Congressional intent as
expressed in the PURPA Conference Report.\413\ However, those holdings
do not address the changes the Commission is implementing here. By
adopting a provision that allows states the option to require variable
avoided cost energy rates, we are not mandating ``utility-type''
regulation. The PURPA Conference Report states that: ``It is not the
intention of the conferees that [QFs] become subject . . . to the type
of examination that is traditionally given to electric utility rate
applications to determine what is the just and reasonable rate that
they should receive for their electric power.'' \414\ Our action today
is consistent with that statement; we are not subjecting QFs to the
same type of examination that is traditionally given to electric
utility rate applications (e.g., cost-of-service rate regulation).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\413\ Harvard Electricity Law Comments at 30.
\414\ Conf. Rep. at 97.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
263. Indeed, the regulation adopted today does not subject QF rates
to any examination whatsoever of the costs incurred by QFs in producing
and selling power. Rather, the variable avoided cost energy rate
provision applicable to QF contracts and other LEOs that is adopted in
this final rule sets QF rates based on the avoided costs
[[Page 54674]]
of the purchasing utility. In no sense can this variable avoided cost
energy rate provision be characterized as imposing utility-style
regulation on the QFs themselves.
264. Finally, we agree with Harvard Electricity Law that state
regulators may not change rates in existing QF contracts or other
existing LEOs.\415\ By its terms, the variable energy avoided cost
provision adopted in this final rule applies only prospectively to new
contracts and new LEOs entered into after the effective date of this
final rule. Nothing in the final rule, including in this preamble,
should be read as sanctioning the modification of existing fixed-rate
QF contracts and LEOs.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\415\ Harvard Electricity Law Comments at 23 (citing API, 461
U.S. at 414).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
d. Whether the Current Approach Has Resulted in Payments to QFs in
Excess of Avoided Costs
i. Comments in Support of NOPR Proposal
265. Duke Energy states that its experience shows the Commission's
original assumption that overestimations and underestimations will
balance out over time was incorrect. From 2012 to 2017, Duke Energy
states that it experienced explosive growth in solar QF contracts, and
entered into at a time of rapidly declining natural gas prices--which
drove down Duke Energy's avoided costs. Duke Energy states that, as of
July 1, 2019, it has almost 4,000 MW of QF power under contract and in
commercial operation. Duke Energy claims the total estimated financial
obligation on Duke Energy's retail and wholesale customers to pay for
this QF power is approximately $4.66 billion over the next
approximately 15 years. If the contracts had been permitted to contain
rates that mirrored the utilities' declining incremental costs either
to generate that electric energy itself or to purchase alternative
electric energy, i.e., Duke Energy's ``actual current avoided costs,''
Duke Energy asserts that the contracts would be valued at $2.4 billion.
Duke Energy claims that, among the factors contributing to this
overpayment of $2.26 billion for the remainder of these QF contracts,
the primary factor has been the requirement to offer fixed avoided cost
energy rates during a period of rapidly declining energy prices.\416\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\416\ Duke Energy Comments at 6.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
266. EEI argues that relying on certain avoided cost methods, such
as the costs of a proxy unit at a fixed point in time, may result, and
has resulted, in the over estimation of future energy prices, leaving
customers saddled with uneconomic PURPA contracts. According to EEI,
the Commission's variable rate proposal will help ensure that the
variable energy rate more accurately reflects the electric utility's
actual avoided cost of energy so that rates for customers are just and
reasonable. EEI describes this change as important for states,
especially those in RTO/ISO markets, that elect to have the avoided
cost rate set at LMP.
267. EEI also submitted with its comments a study performed by
Concentric Energy Advisors showing that the avoided cost rates in the
sample of solar and wind QF contracts they reviewed generally exceeded
rates that are realized in competitive markets for solar and wind
energy. According to that report, the total overpayment ranged between
$2.7 billion and $3.9 billion. Several other commenters also cited the
Concentric Energy Advisors report for the proposition that consumers
nationwide have overpaid for QF contracts between 2009-2018.\417\
Berkshire Hathaway represents that PURPA contracts held by PacifiCorp
will cost customers more than $1.2 billion above projected market costs
over the next 10 years.\418\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\417\ Alliant Energy Comments at 7-8; Conservative Action
Comments at 1; Duke Energy Comments at 5-7; Mr. Moore Comments at 2;
Mr. Transeth Comments at 2.
\418\ Berkshire Hathaway Comments at 5.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
268. Massachusetts DPU argues that a 10-year, fixed energy rate
based on current New England wholesale energy market prices is highly
likely to diverge from actual energy market prices over the ten-year
contract term and could significantly harm ratepayers.\419\ Mr.
Transeth represents that Consumers Energy's QF contracts are priced
between 30 to 50% higher than their current market value.\420\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\419\ Massachusetts DPU Comments at 7 (citing NOPR, 168 FERC ]
61,184 at 40).
\420\ Mr. Transeth Comments at 2.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
269. APPA supports the variable energy rate proposal because the
discrepancy between administratively set, locked-in, long-run avoided
costs and actual market prices for the purchase of equivalent energy
can be enormous, as demonstrated by the evidence submitted in the
Technical Conference. According to APPA, were continued development of
the IPP and renewable industries in jeopardy, the Commission might have
grounds to conclude that enabling QFs to lock in energy payments over
the course of their agreement is needed in order to bolster these
resources, but the growth in the IPP and renewables industries in RTOs/
ISOs indicate otherwise.\421\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\421\ APPA Comments at 16.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
270. Commissioner O'Donnell asserts that the Montana Public Service
Commission has addressed concerns about overpayments by shortening QF
contract length from 25 years to 15, which has resulted in litigation
currently pending before the Montana Supreme Court. Commissioner
O'Donnell asserts that, because the energy component of an avoided cost
rate reflects the price at which the purchasing electric utility could
purchase power on the open market, there is no need to fix that fluid
energy component for as long as 25 years.\422\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\422\ Commissioner O'Donnell Comments at 2.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
271. Competitive Enterprise asserts that long-term fixed price
rates ``serve only to reward certain financial investors at the expense
of consumers, who are forced to pay inflated rates for electricity''
and insists that utilities should only be required to purchase from
resources that are needed and competitively priced.\423\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\423\ Competitive Enterprise Comments at 2.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
ii. Comments in Opposition to NOPR Proposal
272. Harvard Electricity Law observes that the Commission's
examples of contract rates that exceed avoided costs calculated years
prior illustrate the general proposition that ``energy forecasts have a
manifest record of failure.'' \424\ Harvard Electricity Law notes,
however, that in issuing Order No. 69, the Commission recognized that
industry changes are difficult to forecast, but the Commission
nonetheless concluded in Order No. 69 that the possibility that
consumers would be harmed by high rates was outweighed by the
Commission's duty to encourage QFs.\425\ Harvard Electricity Law
further claims that the repeal of the fixed-price rule is not necessary
to protect consumers from rates in future contracts.\426\ Harvard
Electricity Law argues that the Commission's rules do not require an
annual matching between avoided costs and rates, nor prevent states
from setting declining avoided costs (which Order No. 69 explicitly
condones).\427\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\424\ Harvard Electricity Law Comments at 24 (citing Vaclav
Smil, Energy at the Crossroads: Global Perspectives and
Uncertainties, Mass. Inst. Tech., 2003, at 121, 145-149).
\425\ Harvard Electricity Law Comments at 24.
\426\ Id. at 23.
\427\ Id. at 23-24 (citing Order No. 69, FERC Stats. & Regs. ]
30,128 at 30,881).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
273. Several commenters argue that the NOPR's assertion of
artificially high avoided cost rates is unsupported or
[[Page 54675]]
relies on flawed data and analysis.\428\ For example, NIPPC, CREA, REC,
and OSEIA argue that the Commission relied on flawed data and analysis
by using actual market prices that resulted after substantial QF
penetration (which they assert has reduced power prices).\429\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\428\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 30; Public
Interest Organizations Comments at 39-40; Public Interest
Organizations Comments at 43; Solar Energy Industries Comments at
34-36.
\429\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 30-31.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
274. Public Interest Organizations claim that the NOPR's evidence
of overestimations is based on a selective choice of years reflecting
general wholesale price declines, in which QF contracts were executed
just before unforeseen natural gas price declines.\430\ Public Interest
Organizations argue that these recent electricity price overestimations
are not unique to QFs and can be explained by general declines in
natural gas prices since the adoption of hydraulic fracturing and the
2007-2009 recession.\431\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\430\ Public Interest Organizations Comments at 39-40.
\431\ Id. at 47-50.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
275. Public Interest Organizations dispute Alliant's asserted
overestimation by claiming that Alliant likely would have procured non-
QF energy at the same price and further point out that Alliant does not
disclose the data upon which it relies.\432\ Public Interest
Organizations assert that the Commission similarly erred in relying on
EEI's description of overestimations of avoided costs in PacifiCorp's
QF contracts because PacifiCorp only compares those prices to the Mid-C
hub and does ``not contain an analysis of the long-term balancing of
its forecasted avoided energy rates with actual avoided energy costs.''
\433\ Public Interest Organizations contend that this comparison
implies that PacifiCorp would have relied entirely on the Mid-C hub for
all of its needs but for the QF contracts.\434\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\432\ Id. at 40-41.
\433\ Id. at 41 (citing NOPR, 168 FERC ] 61,184 at P 64 n.101
(citing EEI Supplemental Comments, Docket No. AD16-16-000, attach. A
at 3-4 (June 25, 2018))).
\434\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
276. SC Solar Alliance contests Duke Energy's estimate of $2.26
billion in overpayments for QF power. According to SC Solar Alliance,
``an expert witness for South Carolina's Office of Regulatory Staff,
which represents the interests of the using and consuming public in
proceedings before the South Carolina Commission, recently testified
that Duke's estimation of `overpayments' to QFs was not reliable and
that he `wouldn't put a whole lot of weight in [Duke's estimate].' ''
\435\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\435\ SC Solar Alliance Comments at 7 (quoting Public Service
Commission of South Carolina, Docket No. 2019-185 & 186-E, Hearing
Transcript Vol. 2 at 596, lines 6-21 (Horii Test.)) (attached as
Appendix 1 to SC Solar Alliance Comments).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
277. GridLab attacks the conclusions of the Concentric Report,
raising two principal arguments. First, according to GridLab, QF
contracts are executed in non-competitive markets where utilities do
not perform competitive solicitations. If QF avoided cost pricing is
higher than prices set through competitive bidding, GridLab asserts
that is because the utility's production costs are higher than
competitive prices.\436\ Second, GridLab asserts that Concentric has
compared two datasets that are different in several ways, most notably
project size--with larger projects enjoying economies of scale that
result in lower costs. According to GridLab, the difference in project
size and its impact on cost is a significant factor that could account
for the whole of the reported increase on price.\437\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\436\ GridLab Comments at 1-2.
\437\ Id. at 4.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
278. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA argue that it was unreasonable for
the Commission in the NOPR to assume that electricity price declines
are permanent, given recent integrated resource plans (IRP) in the
Northwest predicting significantly increased electricity demand and
market prices at the Mid-C and Palo Verde hubs.\438\ NIPPC, CREA, REC,
and OSEIA represent that electricity prices will climb significantly in
the Northwest. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA also assert that 100%
renewable or non-emitting generation mandates and increased
electrification of transportation could substantially increase
electricity demand. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA contend that fixed-
price QF contracts protect consumers from the potential for future
rising prices, market volatility, market risk, and project risk.\439\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\438\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 33-34.
\439\ Id. at 34-36.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
279. Resources for the Future reasons that ``while fixed prices
determined [five to ten] years ago would likely exceed current average
market prices, that may not be true for fixed prices determined either
more recently or in the future.'' \440\ Resources for the Future states
that, contrary to the NOPR, there is no consensus that wind and solar
generation costs will continue to decline because any capital cost
declines will be relatively modest and will be offset by declining
federal tax credits.\441\ Furthermore, Resources for the Future
attributes these cost declines to the recent U.S. natural gas boom and
points out that this decline is therefore not likely to continue.\442\
sPower similarly argues that recent energy price declines will not
necessarily continue, especially given expiring tax credits and
additional tariffs.\443\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\440\ Resources for the Future Comments at 4.
\441\ Id. at 5.
\442\ Id. at 4.
\443\ sPower Comments at 10-11.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
280. Several commenters assert that the risk of overpayments to QFs
should be compared to the alternative generation sources used by the
utility.\444\ For example, ELCON claims that critics who assert that
QFs are ``locking-in'' consumers to artificially high rates must
acknowledge that utility procurement does exactly the same via the pre-
approval process, sometimes for even longer durations. ELCON argues
that QFs can only benefit consumers by competing on a level playing
field with comparable terms and conditions.\445\ North Carolina
Commission Staff similarly asserts that the risk of overpayment to QFs
should be considered in the context of a utility's long-term commitment
to build plants where ``generation decisions are based upon uncertain
forecasts that could result in ratepayers bearing the same type of
forecast risk from utility plants as they do from QFs.'' \446\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\444\ ELCON Comments at 22; North Carolina Commission Staff
Comments at 2-3; NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 31; Public
Interest Organizations Comments at 40, 43; Solar Energy Industries
Comments at 36-38.
\445\ ELCON Comments at 22.
\446\ North Carolina Commission Staff Comments at 2-3.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
281. According to Solar Energy Industries, the risk from utility
generation construction is allocated to ratepayers for the life of
these assets regardless of ongoing changes in energy prices, while
PURPA was designed to shift this risk away from ratepayers. Solar
Energy Industries state that there is no evidence that ratepayers are
harmed by long-term QF contracts any more than other long-term
contracts or utility recovery of generation assets in their rate base.
Solar Energy Industries state that, even though solar prices have
declined over time, solar QFs should not be penalized for utility
failures to update their avoided cost calculations to keep pace with
such declines.\447\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\447\ Solar Energy Industries Comments at 36-38.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
282. The DC Commission states that, with respect to the fact that
long-term contracts (e.g., 20 years) using fixed avoided energy costs
could create stranded costs potentially due to
[[Page 54676]]
inaccurate projections, the chance of creating stranded costs is
substantially reduced when the most up-to-date data regarding avoided
energy costs is used. The DC Commission states that, if the contract
length is permitted to be flexible, the possibility of stranded costs
would be significantly reduced for shorter term contracts.\448\ The DC
Commission states that, without the worry of stranded costs, there is
no need to eliminate the fixed price contract option for QFs.\449\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\448\ DC Commission Comments at 8.
\449\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
iii. Commission Determination
283. As explained above, the NOPR proposal to give states the
flexibility to require variable energy pricing in QF contracts and
other LEOs, instead of providing QFs the right to elect fixed energy
prices, was based on the Commission's concern that, at least in some
circumstances, long-term fixed avoided cost energy rates have been well
above the purchasing utility's avoided costs for energy--a result
prohibited by PURPA section 210(b). And the record evidence
demonstrates just that, i.e., that QF contract and LEO prices for
energy can exceed and have exceeded avoided costs for energy without
any subsequent balancing out. In addition to the examples presented in
the record of the Technical Conference that were cited in the NOPR,
commenters have provided additional examples of such overpayments, as
described above.\450\ Such evidence has persuaded us that it is
necessary to give states the flexibility to address QF contract and LEO
rates for energy that exceed avoided costs for energy, while at the
same time still allowing states the flexibility to continue requiring
long-term fixed avoided cost energy rates in QF contracts and other
LEOs when such treatment is appropriate.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\450\ See Duke Comments at 6; Idaho Power Comments at 10-11;
Portland General Comments at 5; NOPR, 168 FERC ] 61,184 at P 64
n.101.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
284. As Harvard Electricity Law concedes, the examples of QF
contract rates that exceed avoided costs that are in the record
illustrate the general proposition that ``energy forecasts have a
manifest record of failure.'' \451\ It is this ``manifest record of
failure'' including evidence in the record that the failure has been at
the expense of consumers, that drives us to make the change adopted in
the final rule.\452\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\451\ Harvard Electricity Law Comments at 24 (citing Vaclav
Smil, Energy at the Crossroads: Global Perspectives and
Uncertainties, Mass. Inst. Tech., 2003, at 121, 145-149).
\452\ See, e.g., supra P 254 & note 403.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
285. While some commenters challenge the idea that avoided cost
energy rates in QF contracts and other LEOs have exceeded actual
avoided costs, their arguments largely either concede that
overestimations have occurred while arguing that such overestimations
impacted purchasing electric utilities just as much as QFs, or attempt
to argue that such overestimations were temporary or unusual. For these
reasons, they assert that the Commission should not conclude that
historical overestimations of avoided cost require a change to the
current PURPA Regulations requiring states to allow QFs to fix their
avoided costs energy rates for the term of their contracts. These
arguments do not cause us to reconsider our determination, for the
reasons explained below.
286. First, Harvard Electricity Law's citation to the Commission's
original determination in Order No. 69 that it was not necessary to
provide for variable avoided cost energy rates carries little
weight.\453\ The purpose of the NOPR was to reconsider the Commission's
determinations made in Order No. 69 in light of changes in
circumstances and additional evidence that was not available to the
Commission when it issued Order No. 69 in 1980. The record evidence
cited above demonstrates that, contrary to the Commission's finding in
1980, overestimations and underestimations of future avoided costs may
not even out.\454\ Consequently, the Commission's determination in 1980
does not preclude the Commission from changing the rule adopted at that
time.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\453\ Id. at 23-24 (citing Order No. 69, FERC Stats. & Regs. ]
30,128, at 30,881).
\454\ See Duke Comments at 6; Idaho Power Comments at 10-11;
Portland General Comments at 5; NOPR, 168 FERC ] 61,184 at 64 n.101.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
287. We agree with Public Interest Organizations that the recent
electricity price overestimations were not unique to QFs and can be
explained by general declines in natural gas prices since the adoption
of hydraulic fracturing and the 2007-2009 recession.\455\ But that is
precisely why the estimates of avoided costs reflected in the QF
contracts and LEOs were incorrect and why the resulting fixed avoided
cost energy rates reflected in such QF contracts and other LEOs
resulted in QF rates well above utility avoided costs in violation of
PURPA section 210(b); the precipitous decline in natural gas prices
caused a corresponding reduction in utilities' energy costs, and thus
in their energy avoided costs but this decline was not reflected in the
QFs' fixed contract rates that remained at their previous levels.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\455\ Public Interest Organizations Comments at 47-50.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
288. Similarly, arguments from commenters that electric utilities
also based resource acquisitions on incorrect forecasts of natural gas
prices \456\ ignore a key distinction between utility rates and fixed
QF rates. Electric utilities may have relied on incorrect natural gas
price forecasts to justify the timing and type of their resource
acquisitions, as commenters assert. But once an electric utility
resource decision was made, their cost-based rate regimes typically
obligated the electric utility eventually to pass through to customers
any energy cost savings realized as a result of declining natural gas
and other fuel prices, as well as any energy cost savings due to lower
purchased power rates resulting from the decline in natural gas prices.
By contrast, once QF avoided cost energy rates were fixed based on now-
incorrect (and now-high) natural gas price forecasts, those energy
rates remained fixed for the term of the QFs' contracts and LEOs.
Therefore, unlike fixed avoided cost energy rates in QF contracts and
LEOs, cost-based electric utility energy rates declined as the cost of
natural gas and other fuels and purchased power declined.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\456\ ELCON Comments at 22; North Carolina Commission Staff
Comments at 2-3; NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 31; Public
Interest Organizations Comments at 40, 43; Solar Energy Industries
Comments at 36-38.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
289. We also disagree with Public Interest Organizations'
assertions that it was improper to have used competitive market hub
prices to determine whether fixed QF contract and LEO prices resulted
in overpayments as compared to electric utilities' actual avoided
costs.\457\ We recognize that the competitive market hub prices used in
the comparisons may not have precisely reflected the avoided energy
costs of all electric utilities located in the same region as the
competitive market hub. However, as explained above in the discussion
of the use of Market Hub Prices to determine avoided energy costs,
competitive market prices in general should reflect the marginal
avoided energy costs of utilities with access to such markets.
Certainly, those markets generally reflect the marginal cost of energy
in the region.\458\ The
[[Page 54677]]
magnitude of the differences between the market hub prices and the QF
contract and LEO prices provides solid evidence that the QF contract
and LEO prices used in the comparison were well above actual avoided
energy costs at the time the energy was delivered by the QFs, even if
the exact magnitude is unclear.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\457\ Public Interest Organizations Comments at 40-41.
\458\ A review of recent Mid-C Hub daily spot prices (from
Intercontinental Exchange (ICE) https://www.eia.gov/electricity/wholesale/, indicates that they reflect the marginal cost of energy
in that area since they are usually the result of a significant
number of trades (averaging 54 per day), counterparties (averaging
16 per day), and trading volume (averaging 26,714 MWh/day), which
usually exceed those of the NP-15 trading hub, an active Western
trading hub in Northern California in the CAISO footprint (averaging
6 trades per day, 4 counterparties per day, and 2,756/MWh per day).
The prices for Mid-C ranged between an average of approximately $16/
MWh high price and $13/MWh low price during the recent spring (Mar
19-Jun 20, 2020). During this period the index was reported for 65
trading days for Mid-C and 9 trading days for NP-15.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
290. We acknowledge that energy prices may increase in the future,
as several commenters point out.\459\ However, as noted by Harvard
Electricity Law, ``energy forecasts have a manifest record of
failure.'' \460\ Moreover, the fact that energy prices may increase in
the future does not eliminate the risk that fixed avoided cost energy
rates could still be above actual avoided costs. That is, if the actual
increase in energy prices is still lower than the forecasted increase
that would form the basis of the fixed avoided cost energy rate, then
the fixed avoided cost energy rate will be above actual avoided energy
costs. Giving states the flexibility to require variable avoided cost
energy rates in QF contracts and in other LEOs will allow states to
better ensure that avoided cost energy payments made to QFs will more
accurately reflect the purchasing utility's avoided costs regardless of
whether energy prices are increasing or declining. We also note that,
if energy prices do in fact increase, variable avoided cost energy
pricing would protect and even benefit the QF itself, as it would not
be locked into a fixed energy rate contract or LEO that would be below
the purchasing electric utility's avoided energy cost.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\459\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 33-36; Resources
for the Future Comments at 4; sPower comments at 10-11.
\460\ Harvard Electricity Law Comments at 24 (citing Vaclav
Smil, Energy at the Crossroads: Global Perspectives and
Uncertainties, Mass. Inst. Tech., 2003, at 121, 145-149).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
291. Although many commenters agreed that fixed QF energy rates
were higher than actual avoided energy costs in at least some
instances, challenges were raised against both Duke Energy's estimate
that its fixed QF contract rates were $2.6 billion above market costs,
and the Concentric Report's comparison of QF fixed rates for wind and
solar facilities with the cost of wind and solar projects with
competitive, non-PURPA contracts.
292. However, the expert testimony cited by the SC Solar Alliance,
that the witness ``wouldn't put a whole lot of weight in [Duke's
estimate],'' \461\ does not address Duke's calculation of past
overpayments. Rather, the witness was answering a question regarding
the potential for overpayments ``[f]or going forward solar,'' i.e.,
future overpayments as a result of the new fixed avoided cost rates
being considered by the South Carolina Commission that were the subject
of the expert witness' testimony.\462\ The same witness acknowledged
the past overpayments made by Duke Energy, which he attributed to
``drops in natural gas prices that no one could've foreseen.'' \463\ It
is these overpayments due to unforeseen declines in natural gas prices
that form an important basis for the Commission's determination in this
final rule to now give states the flexibility to require variable
avoided cost energy rates in QF contracts and LEOs.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\461\ SC Solar Alliance Comments at 7 (quoting, Public Service
Commission of South Carolina, Docket No. 2019-185 & 186-E, Hearing
Transcript Vol. 2, Tr. at 596: 6-21 (Horii Test)) (attached as
Appendix 1 to SC Solar Alliance Comments).
\462\ Public Service Commission of South Carolina, Docket No.
2019-185 & 186-E, Hearing Transcript Vol. 2, Tr. 596: 3-4 (Horii
Test)) (attached as Appendix 1 to SC Solar Alliance Comments).
\463\ Id. at 593:21-22.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
293. With respect to the criticisms of the Concentric Report, we
emphasize that we have not relied on that report to support the
variable energy avoided cost provision adopted in the final rule. It is
not clear that the lower cost of the competitively priced renewable
resources identified in the report represents the avoided costs of the
purchasing utilities that entered into the QF contracts at fixed rates
for renewable resources under PURPA. Therefore, it is not clear that
the difference in costs identified by Concentric can be ascribed to the
fixed rates in the QF contracts or rather to the fact that the avoided
cost rates in the QF contracts were based on more expensive non-
renewable capacity that was avoided by the purchasing utilities.
e. Whether the Proposed Change Would Violate the Statutory Requirement
that the PURPA Regulations Encourage QFs
i. Comments
294. Several commenters argue that the NOPR's variable rate
proposal is inconsistent with PURPA's mandate that the PURPA
Regulations ``encourage'' the development of QFs.\464\ Southeast Public
Interest Organizations state that removing QFs' right to a fixed energy
rate would flout Congressional intent that PURPA encourage QF
development because fixed rates are necessary to attract QF
financing.\465\ Harvard Electricity Law states that Congress's mandate
to encourage QFs is not contingent on industry conditions and does not
expire.\466\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\464\ Allco Comments at 9; Con Edison at 3, 4; Harvard
Electricity Law Comments at 1; North American-Central Comments at 4-
6; Southeast Public Interest Organizations at 9-11.
\465\ Southeast Public Interest Organizations Comments at 9-10.
\466\ Harvard Electricity Law Comments at 1.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
ii. Commission Determination
295. As explained above in Section IV.A.1, the statutory
requirement that the Commission's PURPA Regulations encourage QFs
remains, but it is bounded by the statutory provision in PURPA section
210(b) that QF rates may not exceed a purchasing utility's avoided
costs. Further, as explained above, we have determined, based on the
record evidence, that it is not necessarily the case that
overestimations and underestimations of avoided energy costs will
balance out. Consequently, a fixed energy rate in a QF contract or LEO
potentially could violate the statutory avoided cost cap on QF rates.
296. The Commission's PURPA Regulations continue to encourage the
development of QFs by, among other things, allowing a state to vary the
rate paid to the QF over time but in a way that satisfies the rate cap
established in PURPA section 210(b). In this way, the QF can obtain a
higher rate when the utility's avoided costs increase, and ratepayers
are not paying more than the utility's avoided costs when prices
decrease. Furthermore, as discussed above, allowing the use of variable
energy rates may promote longer contract terms, which would help
encourage and support QFs.\467\ It therefore is consistent with PURPA
section 210(b), as well as the obligation imposed by PURPA section
210(a) to revise the Commission's PURPA Regulations ``from time to
time,'' to provide the states the flexibility to require that QF
contracts and other LEOs implement variable avoided cost energy rates
in order to prevent payments to QFs in excess of the purchasing
electric utility's avoided energy costs. PURPA section 210(b) prohibits
the Commission from requiring QF rates above avoided costs even if,
according to some commenters, a fixed avoided cost energy rate would
provide greater encouragement to QFs than a variable avoided cost
energy rate.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\467\ See infra P 349.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
[[Page 54678]]
f. Discrimination
i. Comments in Support of NOPR Proposal
297. Alliant Energy observes that utility-owned generation and
traditional power purchase agreements (PPAs) are subject to a
demonstration of need and that traditional PPAs are subject to re-
evaluation during their term to determine whether they continue to be
cost-competitive and in the best interests of customers. Alliant Energy
asserts that, by contrast, QFs are not required to demonstrate that
their projects are needed and that, once a contract is executed, it is
not subject to re-evaluation.\468\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\468\ Alliant Energy Comments at 6-7.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
ii. Comments in Opposition to NOPR Proposal
298. Several commenters assert that the NOPR's variable avoided
cost energy rate proposal is discriminatory.\469\ For example, EPSA
argues that PURPA requires the Commission to implement regulations
that, for rates for electric utility purchases from QFs, ``shall not
discriminate against qualifying cogenerators or qualifying small power
producers.'' EPSA describes this standard as more restrictive than the
FPA's prohibition against ``unduly discriminatory'' rates. According to
EPSA, the fact that long-term QF contracts are substantially above
prevailing market prices due to declining wholesale prices over the
long-term does not justify the variable rate proposal because electric
utility-owned generation is similarly based on imperfect long-term
forecasts of energy prices that oftentimes prove to be too high. EPSA
therefore argues that the NOPR variable rate proposal should not be
adopted unless utility-owned assets are also subject to a similar cost
recovery regime.\470\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\469\ ELCON Comments at 21-22; SC Solar Alliance Comments at 5-
10; sPower Comments at 13; see also ELCON Comments at 22; North
Carolina Commission Staff Comments at 2-3; NIPPC, CREA, REC, and
OSEIA Comments at 31; Public Interest Organizations Comments at 40,
43; Solar Energy Industries Comments at 36-38.
\470\ EPSA Comments at 8-9.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
299. sPower describes the NOPR proposal to allow variable rates as
providing a significant advantage to electric utilities over QFs, given
that electric utilities themselves, according to sPower, have not had
to lower rates to consumers as energy prices have declined.\471\ ELCON
asserts that pushing more market risk to QFs while utility assets
remain insulated from markets creates an investment risk asymmetry.
ELCON claims this puts QFs at a competitive disadvantage and shifts the
consumer burden to more utility builds, which have generally been
higher cost than merchant builds.\472\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\471\ sPower Comments at 13.
\472\ ELCON Comments at 21-22.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
300. SC Solar Alliance states that utilities often rely on fuel
price forecasts over time to justify rate base approval for generation
assets that might run beyond price forecasts. SC Solar Alliance argues
that allowing utilities this right, but not QFs, holds QFs to a much
higher standard than utilities and therefore is discriminatory.\473\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\473\ SC Solar Alliance Comments at 5-10.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
301. Commissioner Slaughter argues that, by removing the fixed,
long-term contract option for independent power producers, the NOPR
threatens to hamper the competitiveness of renewable-based energy firms
challenging vertically integrated utilities in many localities across
the country.\474\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\474\ Commissioner Slaughter Comments at 4.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
iii. Commission Determination
302. The discrimination claims are based on the incorrect
assumption that electric utilities have not been required to lower
their energy rates as prices have declined. To the contrary, as
explained above, utilities typically charge their customers cost-based
rates, and as their fuel and purchased power costs have declined, they
typically have been required to provide corresponding reductions in the
energy portion of their rates to their customers.\475\ Requiring QF
avoided cost energy rates to likewise change as purchasing electric
utilities' avoided energy costs change does not create a discriminatory
difference, but rather puts QF rates on par with utility rates.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\475\ See supra PP 40, 122, 288.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
303. Further, we are not changing the requirement that QF avoided
cost energy rates be set at the purchasing utility's full avoided
energy costs. As the Supreme Court held in API, ``the full-avoided-cost
rule plainly satisfies the nondiscrimination requirement.'' \476\
Rather, we are allowing the states the option to now choose to require
QF avoided cost energy rates that vary with the purchasing utility's
avoided costs of energy, rather than QF avoided cost rates that are
fixed for the life of the QF's contract or LEO, to ensure the rates
comply with PURPA.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\476\ API, 461 U.S. at 413.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
g. Effect of Variable Energy Rates on Financing
i. Comments in Support of the NOPR Proposal
304. Several commenters state that fixed energy payments are not
necessary for QFs to obtain financing.\477\ Alliant states that it is
on track to be the third largest utility owner-operator of wind
facilities in the United States, with 1.9 GW on its system and in
addition is increasing the pace of solar resource development in its
Wisconsin territory. Alliant states it therefore does not believe that
the proposed change will slow renewable deployment and adoption.\478\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\477\ APPA Comments at 16-17; Indiana Commission Comments at 6.
\478\ Alliant Energy Comments at 6.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
305. Several commenters assert that PURPA's must-purchase
requirement itself should necessarily afford QF developers a degree of
certainty and enables developers to attract capital at advantageous
terms.\479\ The Idaho Commission states that, even if modified as
proposed, QF contract terms would remain superior to competitively bid
renewable projects where the energy is not ``must take'' and
curtailment and other reliability parameters are imposed.\480\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\479\ APPA Comments at 16-17; Finadvice Comments at 2; Idaho
Commission Comments at 4; Commissioner O'Donnell Comments at 3.
\480\ Idaho Commission Comments at 4.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
306. Finadvice and APPA argue that maintaining a fixed capacity
rate, as proposed by the Commission, will help attract capital and
ameliorate any negative effect that the variable energy rate proposal
may impose.\481\ Ohio Commission Energy Advocate argues, as evidence
that QFs can still flourish under a variable energy rate, that the PJM
market has successfully attracted new supplies and ensured resource
adequacy through fixed capacity and variable energy rates.\482\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\481\ APPA Comments at 16-17; Finadvice Comments at 2.
\482\ Ohio Commission Energy Advocate Comments at 3-4.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
307. The Idaho Commission states that variable energy prices
protect the ratepayer while allowing the QF to ensure a stream of
revenue through a longer-term contract. The Idaho Commission affirms
that the rapid growth of non-QF renewable projects and their ability to
obtain financing should quell any concerns about a QF's ability to
obtain financing as long as PURPA's ``must take'' provision
remains.\483\ Commissioner O'Donnell asserts that QFs should bear some
market risk as energy prices rise and fall in a way that balances risks
to all parties.\484\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\483\ Idaho Commission Comments at 4.
\484\ Commissioner O'Donnell Comments at 3.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
308. EEI argues that PURPA does not require the Commission or the
states to implement regulations that guarantee a
[[Page 54679]]
QF's financeability. EEI represents that Congress intended QFs to be
treated similarly to merchant generation and simply required QFs to
have non-discriminatory access. According to EEI, because QFs are not
subjected to the oversight or regulatory responsibilities applicable to
electric utilities, it was not expected or intended that QFs be treated
the same as electric utilities.\485\ Similarly, Duke argues that the
central design criteria for PURPA rates and terms should be customer
indifference, just and reasonableness, and non-discrimination. Duke
Energy states that a design that requires QF financeability as a
criterion will inevitably lead to a QF boom and customer harm.\486\
Duke Energy further asserts that several factors affect financeability
and that, therefore, claims by QFs that they require fixed energy
payments for financing purposes should be rejected.\487\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\485\ EEI Comments at 35.
\486\ Duke Energy Comments at 17-18.
\487\ Id. at 13.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
309. EEI claims QFs that require third-party financing will still
be able to obtain financing if the Commission adopts the proposals in
the NOPR, because they are additional options, in addition to those
currently being used by states, that will be available to determine
avoided costs. EEI maintains that a QF developer will be able to obtain
financing under any of the options, provided it can build a cost-
efficient plant that can profit at an avoided cost rate.\488\ EEI
claims that independent power producers lacking the certainty of the
mandatory purchase obligation are building most renewable generation
today because merchant power plants may be developed and financed using
a variety of hedging and risk management tools, such as commodity
hedges, that lock in cash flows and facilitate construction at the
outset.\489\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\488\ EEI Comments at 35-36.
\489\ Id. at 36.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
310. APPA states that much of the renewable development that has
occurred over the past 20 years has taken place within RTO/ISO
footprints and therefore is largely unaided by PURPA obligations.\490\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\490\ APPA Comments at 16-17.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
311. Duke Energy states that concern about the potential for fixed
avoided cost contract rates exceeding actual avoided costs at the time
of delivery have led both North Carolina and South Carolina to enact
laws placing limits on the length of QF contracts.\491\ The Idaho
Commission states that there is no evidence that variable energy prices
would be fatal to QF development.\492\ The Idaho Commission states that
it reduced contract length on large projects to two years because it
did not interpret the Commission's current rules to allow for a
variable energy rate inside a long-term contract. The Idaho Commission
states that, because its experience dictated that the longer the
contract term, the more inflated the avoided cost rate, the Idaho
Commission set parameters to balance QF interests against utility
ratepayer interests. The Idaho Commission states that an energy rate
established at the time of contract formation that provides for
``revisions to the energy rate at regular intervals, consistent with,
for example, a purchasing electric utility's [integrated resource
planning (IRP)] to reflect updated avoided cost calculations'' would
allow states to consider longer term contracts without putting
ratepayers at risk.\493\ NorthWestern represents that the Montana
Commission has lowered the length of QF contracts from 25 to 15 years
in response to the current requirement that QFs are entitled to fixed
avoided cost rates for energy in their contracts and a concern that
rates calculated at the time a contract is signed are likely to change
over the life of that contract.\494\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\491\ Duke Energy Comments at 9; LG&E/KU Comments at 4.
\492\ Idaho Commission Comments at 4.
\493\ Id. (citing NOPR, 168 FERC ] 61,184 at P 5 n.5).
\494\ NorthWestern Comments at 6-7.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
ii. Comments in Opposition to the NOPR Proposal
312. Many commenters assert that the NOPR's variable energy rate
proposal will result in QFs being unable to obtain financing.\495\
Several commenters also assert that it is discriminatory that utilities
and non-QF generators can rate-base long-term investments and recover
actual operating costs, while the NOPR's proposed rules would deprive
QFs of a reasonable ability to forecast their cost recovery with no
guarantees.\496\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\495\ Allco Comments at 9; AllEarth Comments at 2; Biogas
Comments at 2; BluEarth Comments at 2; Biological Diversity Comments
at 8; Commissioner Slaughter Comments at 4; Con Edison Comments at
3, 4; Covanta Comments at 7-8; DC Commission Comments at 6-8;
Distributed Sun Comments at 1; EPSA Comments at 2; Energy Recovery
at 4; Harvard Electricity Law Comments at 5; Massachusetts AG
Comments at 8-9; New England Hydro Comments at 8; NIPPC, CREA, REC,
and OSEIA Comments at 37-38; North Carolina DOJ Comments at 3, 6;
North American-Central Comments at 4-6; Public Interest
Organizations Comments at 6-7; Resources for the Future Comments at
6-7. SC Solar Alliance Comments at 5-7; Southeast Public Interest
Organizations Comments at 9-11; State Entities Comments at 2-3; Two
Dot Wind Comments at 11-13.
\496\ Allco Comments at 9; Commissioner Slaughter at 4; Harvard
Electricity Law Comments at 5; NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments
at 36-37; Public Interest Organizations Comments at 6-7; Solar
Energy Industries at 29-30.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
313. Several commenters assert that the NOPR lacks evidence on the
record to conclude that the variable rate proposal would not affect the
ability of QFs to obtain financing.\497\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA
argue that the NOPR contained no record evidence demonstrating how this
proposal would continue to encourage QFs in a non-discriminatory
manner,\498\ and lacks evidence on how QF generation can be financed
without a fixed energy rate.\499\ Similarly, Harvard Electricity Law
asserts that repealing the fixed-price PPA requirement is premised on
irrelevant data and ignores the record, and disagrees with the
Commission's demonstration of information on non-QF capacity to show
that QF development no longer relies on contracts with fixed energy
rates.\500\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\497\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 29, 46; Harvard
Electricity Law Comments at 22, 25-27; Public Interest Organizations
Comments at 6-7, 33-35.
\498\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 29.
\499\ Id. at 46-48.
\500\ Harvard Electricity Law Comments at 22, 25 (citing NOPR,
168 FERC ] 61,184 at PP 69-70, 76).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
314. Public Interest Organizations assert that testimony from
Southern Company, American Forest and Paper Association, and Solar
Energy Industries, upon which the NOPR relies, states that non-QF
renewable PPAs generally entail fixed energy rates rather than variable
energy rates.\501\ In particular, Public Interest Organizations state
that testimony from Solar Energy Industries, refers to reliance on
fixed rates for energy and/or capacity without describing them as
alternatives but rather ``an acknowledgement that a [power purchase
agreement] may provide fixed capacity in addition to fixed energy
revenue, not a suggestion that a QF can be developed without a
predictable energy revenue stream.'' \502\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\501\ Public Interest Organizations Comments at 33-35 (citing
NOPR, 168 FERC ] 61,184, at P 70 n.114 (citing Tech. Conference,
Docket No. AD16-16-000, Tr. at 153, 200 (filed June 30, 2016))).
\502\ Id. at 35 (citing NOPR, 168 FERC ] 61,184, at P 70 n.115
(citing Solar Energy Industries Comments, Docket No. AD16-16-000, at
3 (filed June 30, 2016))).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
315. Allco describes programs in California, Massachusetts,
Connecticut, and Vermont that offer standard QF contract programs with
variable energy rates, none of which, according to Allco, have led to
the construction of solar projects.\503\ Allco claims that these
programs prove that, without the ability to obtain a fixed long-term
forecasted rate, QF solar energy development will
[[Page 54680]]
not exist.\504\ Southeast Public Interest Organizations assert that
Southeastern states with fixed QF energy rates have seen vigorous QF
development, while Southeastern states with variable energy rates have
seen virtually no QF development, undermining the Commission's
assertion that QFs can be financed without fixed energy rates.\505\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\503\ Allco Comments at 10.
\504\ Id. at 9-11.
\505\ Southeast Public Interest Organizations Comments at 9-11,
15-16.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
316. Covanta and Energy Recovery state that the NOPR's variable
rate proposal would have an especially negative effect on Waste to
Energy facilities.\506\ Covanta states that, because Waste to Energy
depends on finite local tax resources, a loss in energy revenue due to
price variability cannot be easily replaced.\507\ Covanta states that,
without adequate QF pricing and multi-year contracts (and consistent,
predictable pricing throughout the life of the contract), local
governments may be forced to close their Waste to Energy facilities
prematurely, to minimize loss and stranding that investment.\508\
Energy Recovery states that the inability to secure suitable rates
through a long-term contract has closed seventeen Waste to Energy
facilities in the last fifteen years.\509\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\506\ Covanta Comments at 7-8; Energy Recovery Comments at 1, 4.
\507\ Covanta Comments at 7-8.
\508\ Id. at 8.
\509\ Energy Recovery Comments at 3.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
317. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA state that the NOPR's anecdotal
reliance on tax incentives to encourage QF development is irrelevant
because these incentives are declining or disappearing, thereby
requiring QFs to rely even more on energy rates.\510\ NIPPC, CREA, REC,
and OSEIA predict that the NOPR's proposed rules would make QF
development riskier and would thereby slow the development of new
technologies such as energy storage, hydrogen fuels, and other advanced
renewable energy technologies.\511\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\510\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 40-41.
\511\ Id. at 41-42.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
318. Solar Energy Industries states that financing for QFs differs
from financing for fossil fuel generators because ``much of the cost of
installation is incurred up-front, but once installed, the generation
has little, if any, variable cost.'' \512\ Likewise, Harvard
Electricity Law observes that wind and solar QFs, for example, have
higher capital costs, lower operating costs, and provide energy
intermittently, and therefore have characteristics that may present
different financing challenges as compared to non-QF natural gas fired
capacity.\513\ Similarly, Public Interest Organizations argue that,
unlike independent power producer natural gas generators with fixed
capacity payments and variable energy costs, renewable QFs rely on
fixed energy payments to cover their capital costs given their own
nominal variable energy costs.\514\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\512\ Solar Energy Industries Comments at 30.
\513\ Harvard Electricity Law Comments at 26.
\514\ Public Interest Organizations Comments at 33-34.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
319. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA state that the financeability of
generation with fixed capacity prices and variable energy prices inside
RTOs/ISOs is irrelevant to regions that lie outside of RTOs/ISOs.\515\
NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA criticize the NOPR's reliance on an
independent power producer natural gas turbine's financeability outside
the RTO/ISO context as irrelevant to QFs because these natural gas
turbines receive fixed capacity payments and variable energy payments
to account for the fluctuating price of fuel; whereas a QF would need a
sufficient fixed capacity payment to support financing and an energy
rate that removes market risk.\516\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\515\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 42-43.
\516\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
320. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA state that the NOPR's reference to
hedging instruments to reduce risks from fluctuating prices is
irrelevant.\517\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA state that hedging makes
projects less financeable because it increases transaction and
compliance costs for small power producer QFs that cannot afford large
legal divisions and trading floors to employ such hedges.\518\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\517\ Id. at 44-45 (citing NOPR, 168 FERC ] 61,184 at P 72 &
n.117).
\518\ Id. at 45-46.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
321. Resources for the Future states that wind projects have used
bank hedges, synthetic PPAs, and proxy revenue swaps.\519\ Resources
for the Future claims, however, that these products would be
inaccessible to most wind QFs if fixed energy payments are eliminated.
Resources for the Future argues that solar QFs would have even less
access to such hedging given their smaller size and high transaction
costs. Resources for the Future states that QFs under 5 MW in RTO/ISOs
and QFs outside of RTO/ISOs thus would be unable to obtain
financing.\520\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\519\ Resources for the Future Comments at 6.
\520\ Id. at 6-7.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
322. Solar Energy Industries states that QFs in RTO/ISO markets
without a fixed energy rate would require a hedging instrument to
finance their projects. Solar Energy Industries further states that QFs
outside RTO/ISO markets without a fixed energy rate would be unable to
finance their projects because they would have no access to such
hedging mechanisms.\521\ Solar Energy Industries states that the NOPR
failed to consider which markets offer financial products, whether
these financial products are available to QFs outside RTOs/ISOs, and
whether these products will be sufficient to provide financing to
QFs.\522\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\521\ Solar Energy Industries Comments at 30.
\522\ Id. at 31.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
323. Solar Energy Industries states that financing for QFs differs
from financing for fossil fuel generators because much of the cost of
installation is incurred up-front, with virtually no variable costs.
Solar Energy Industries states that, because of this difference,
financiers ``examine the QF's projected revenue stream to ensure that
the revenue stream is sufficient to recover the installed costs plus a
competitive return.'' \523\ Solar Energy Industries reasons that QFs
must therefore know in advance their facility's energy and capacity
values and obtain a legally enforceable contract that fits into common
underwriting models.\524\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\523\ Id.
\524\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
324. North Carolina DOJ asserts that allowing avoided cost energy
prices to fluctuate could eliminate fixed-price power sales contracts,
thereby making compensation to QFs more volatile and discouraging
renewable energy financing.\525\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\525\ North Carolina DOJ Comments at 3.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
325. Distributed Sun agrees with Commissioner Glick's dissent on
the NOPR that revoking the fixed energy price requirement would halt
the construction of most distributed energy resources.\526\ Solar
Energy Industries states that it is not aware of a meaningful number of
QFs that have been constructed using capacity rates alone or capacity
rates with variable energy rates.\527\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\526\ Distributed Sun Comments at 3.
\527\ Solar Energy Industries Comments at 28.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
326. Mr. Mattson argues that a variable rate or a rate based on a
projected stream of revenues during the contract are not long-term
contracts. Mr. Mattson argues that this violates legislative intent and
precedent and is not viable, suggesting that PURPA requires avoided
cost data to be kept by a utility for public inspection.\528\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\528\ Mr. Mattson Comments at 26.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
327. Western Resource Councils represents that PURPA, in the rural
[[Page 54681]]
Northern Plains and Rocky Mountain West, is the only vehicle for small
businesses to obtain project financing and that variable rates
undermine the certainty of QFs obtaining financing.\529\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\529\ Western Resource Councils Comments at 2.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
328. Public Interest Organizations assert that the NOPR has no
basis to speculate that the Idaho Commission shortened contract lengths
to two years because of the fixed rate requirement or that it would
provide longer contracts if it could require variable energy
rates.\530\ According to Public Interest Organizations, the fact that
no solar and wind QFs have been developed since the Idaho Commission
set a two year contract length, even while they are currently entitled
to fixed rates, shows that allowing variable rates will further
discourage wind and solar QF development.\531\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\530\ Public Interest Organizations Comments at 36.
\531\ Id. at 35-38.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
329. sPower argues that, even with long-term contracts, QFs will
not be viable without fixed energy rates and explains that, if the
Commission seeks to encourage states to offer longer contract terms, it
should just require longer terms.\532\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\532\ sPower Comments at 11.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
330. The DC Commission states that, in the jurisdictions where the
contract length has been adjusted to ``short-term,'' such as Idaho's
two-year contract,\533\ further elimination of the QF fixed price
contract option would discourage or eliminate new small renewable
energy facilities entering the markets, which is not consistent with
PURPA's objective of encouraging the construction of renewable
generation.\534\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\533\ DC Commission Comments at 8 (citing NOPR, 168 FERC ]
61,184 at P 77).
\534\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
331. NIPPC, CREA, REC, OSEIA, and Public Interest Organizations
argue that the fact that states have shortened the length of QF
contracts in response to fixed energy prices means that the Commission
should require a minimum contract length.\535\ Green Power supports the
creation of longer-term standard contract lengths for both cogeneration
and small power production facilities.\536\ Green Power recommends that
cogeneration developers are offered 5, 8, or 10-year contracts and that
small power producers developers are offered 10, 15, or 20-year
contracts.\537\ Mr. Mattson proposes that long-term contracts, defined
as 20 years or longer, be available to QFs at their discretion.\538\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\535\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 47-48; Public
Interest Organizations Comments at 6-7.
\536\ Green Power Comments at 2, 10.
\537\ Id. at 10.
\538\ Mr. Mattson Comments at 7-9.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
332. CARE notes that a purchasing utility's fixed capacity value
may be zero if the state determines that the electric utility has no
need for additional capacity resources. In that circumstance, there
would be no fixed element in an avoided cost contract, which CARE
believes would be inconsistent with the Commission's rationale
justifying variable energy rate contracts.\539\ EPSA similarly argues
that, as noted in the NOPR, an electric utility is not required to pay
for QF capacity that the state has determined is not needed. EPSA
claims that the variable rate proposal therefore would create
substantial uncertainty for QF developers and investors in non-ISO/RTO
regions.\540\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\539\ CARE Comments at 4 n.7.
\540\ EPSA Comments at 12.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
333. American Biogas argues that LMP prices are not sufficient to
sustain existing biogas projects or to increase their number.\541\
Several commenters state that LMP cannot sustain QFs in general.\542\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\541\ Biogas Comments at 2.
\542\ BluEarth Renewables Comments at 2; Biological Diversity at
8; Covanta Comments at 9; Public Interest Organization Comments at
43-44.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
334. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA argue that the NOPR proposal to
base QF pricing on LMP or Western EIM will limit competition, because
QFs will be stuck with no long-term assurance of investment recovery,
and thus with no means to finance their projects, while regulated
incumbent utilities will be able to rate-base their generation assets,
thus guaranteeing long-term recovery of their investments.\543\ NIPPC,
CREA, REC, and OSEIA maintain that prices for long-term QF contracts
should be set by reference to long-term price indices or other
indicators that, unlike highly-variable LMP and Western EIM prices,
genuinely reflect the long-term costs of generation avoided by the
purchasing utility.\544\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\543\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 55-56.
\544\ Id. at 53.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
iii. Commission Determination
335. As an initial matter, the Commission agrees with commenters
that PURPA does not guarantee QFs a rate that guarantees financing.
PURPA only requires the Commission to adopt rules that encourage the
development of QFs; it does not provide a guarantee that any particular
QF will be developed or profitable. This is evident from the structure
of PURPA, which caps QF rates at the purchasing utility's avoided costs
rather than providing for rates that guarantee the recovery of a QF's
costs. The legislative history confirms that Congress did not intend to
guarantee QF financing. As stated in the PURPA Conference Report, ``the
Conferees recognize that [QFs] are different from electric utilities,
not being guaranteed a rate of return on their activities generally or
on the activities vis-a-vis the sale of power to the utility and whose
risk in proceeding forward in the [QF] enterprise is not guaranteed to
be recoverable.'' \545\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\545\ Conf. Rep. at 97-98 (emphasis added).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
336. Notwithstanding that PURPA does not guarantee QF
financeability, the Commission believes that the variable avoided cost
energy rate option implemented by this final rule will still allow QFs
to obtain financing.
337. Before addressing specific comments on this issue, however, we
reiterate that we are not eliminating fixed rate pricing for QFs. Under
this final rule, QFs will continue to be able to require fixed avoided
cost capacity rates in their contracts and LEOs. Capacity costs, as
relevant here, include the cost of constructing the capacity being
avoided by purchasing utilities as a consequence of their purchases
from QFs. As will be discussed below, a combination of fixed avoided
cost capacity rates and variable energy rates can provide important
revenue streams that can support the financing of QFs.
338. Furthermore, merely because QFs have had access to fixed
avoided cost energy rates does not mean that QFs must have access to
such rates to obtain future financing. Up to now, QFs have had the
right under the PURPA Regulations to both fixed capacity and fixed
energy rates, and we understand that most QFs executing long-term
contracts have exercised this right. Commenters insisting that the
Commission cannot allow states the option to impose variable avoided
cost energy rates without evidence that QFs have obtained financing
under such contract structures \546\ are attempting to impose a
standard that could never be satisfied.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\546\ See Solar Energy Industries Comments at 28; NIPPC, CREA,
REC, and OSEIA Comments at 29, 46; Harvard Electricity Law Comments
at 22, 25-27; Public Interest Organizations Comments at 6-7, 33-35.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
339. In any event, there is ample evidence outside of the PURPA
context demonstrating that generation projects with fixed capacity
rate-variable energy contracts are financeable. As the Commission
explained in detail in the NOPR, since the time of the passage of PURPA
a large new independent power production industry has developed in
[[Page 54682]]
the United States. Like QFs, independent power producers sell power at
wholesale, and have no ability to rate-base their facilities or to
otherwise recover their costs through regulated rates to retail
customers, unlike traditional utilities with franchised service
territories and retail customers. Unlike QFs, however, independent
power producers have had no right to require utilities to purchase
their power or to impose fixed energy cost pricing in their power sales
contracts.\547\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\547\ See NOPR, 168 FERC ] 61,184 at P 76.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
340. The record shows that, even without the right to require long-
term fixed energy rates, non-QF independent power producers
nevertheless have been able to obtain financing for large amounts of
generation capacity, including from renewables. EIA data shows that, in
2019, approximately 44% of all energy produced by natural gas-fired
generation in the United States was generated by independently owned
capacity.\548\ Furthermore, EIA data demonstrates that net generation
of energy by non-utility owned renewable resources in the United States
grew by almost 700% between 2005 and 2018, which speaks to the reality
that renewable resources are able to acquire financing even without the
right to require long-term fixed energy rates.\549\ Based on this data,
we find that the right to require counterparties to pay fixed energy
rates is not essential for the financing of independent power
generation capacity.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\548\ EIA, Electric Power Monthly with Data for December 2018,
at tbl. 1.7.B (February 2020), https://www.eia.gov/electricity/monthly/archive/february2020.pdf).
\549\ Id. P 74 (explaining that net generation of energy by non-
utility owned renewable resources in the United States escalated
from 51.7 TWh in 2005 when EPAct 2005 was passed, to 340 TWh in
2018) (citing EIA, Electricity Data Browser, www.eia.gov/electricity/data/browser).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
341. We acknowledge that a number of different financing mechanisms
were used for this independent power generation capacity, not all of
which will be available to QFs. Nevertheless, we understand that a
standard rate structure employed in the electric industry is a fixed
capacity rate-variable energy rate structure, and that many independent
power production facilities have been financed based on this
structure.\550\ Accordingly, record evidence and historical data
regarding the financing and construction of significant amounts of
independent power production facilities supports the Commission's
conclusion that a fixed capacity rate-variable energy rate structure--
which will apply in those states choosing the variable avoided cost
energy rate option--also will support financing of QFs.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\550\ American Public Power Association, How New Generation is
Funded (Aug. 29, 2018), https://www.publicpower.org/blog/how-new-generation-funded (``Beginning in 2015, merchant generation [in
RTOs/ISOs markets] began to increase dramatically from prior years,
amounting to 19.3 percent of new capacity in 2015, 7.2 percent in
2016, and 29.1 percent in 2017.''). In RTOs and ISOs with capacity
markets, merchant generators are compensated through variable energy
rates and fixed capacity rates, along with whatever ancillary
service revenues they can earn.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
342. For the reasons described below, we do not find compelling the
concerns expressed by some commenters that a fixed capacity rate-
variable energy rate construct may not work for solar and wind
resources, which have high fixed capacity costs and minimal variable
energy costs.\551\ Similarly, we are not persuaded by comments that
point out that energy rates in typical independent power production
contracts are designed to recover the cost of a facility's fuel,
whereas variable energy rates would provide no such guarantee.\552\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\551\ See Harvard Electricity Law Comments at 26; Public
Interest Organizations Comments at 33-34; Solar Energy Industries
Comments at 30.
\552\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 42-43.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
343. As an initial matter, as we have noted, the record
demonstrates that the amount of renewable resources being developed
outside of PURPA greatly exceeds the amount of renewable resources
developed as QFs.\553\ Renewable resources developed outside of PURPA
may not have a legal right to long-term contracts with fixed energy
rates, yet nevertheless have been able to obtain financing.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\553\ See supra P 240.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
344. The Commission also disagrees with those commenters who assert
that, as a consequence of the above factors, the Commission should
``require[] the variable energy component to be structured in a way
that removes market risk from the QF.'' \554\ This argument runs
directly counter to one of the fundamental premises of PURPA, which is
that QFs must accept the market risk associated with their projects by
being paid no more than the purchasing utility's avoided cost, thereby
preventing utility retail customers from subsidizing QFs.\555\ PURPA
does not allow the Commission to require QFs to be paid rates above
avoided costs in order to make certain types of QF technologies
financeable. If a state determines that it is necessary to require
variable avoided cost energy rates in order to avoid paying QFs an
above-avoided cost rate, which is a bedrock requirement of PURPA, then
the impact this may have on facilities not financeable with a fixed
capacity rate-variable energy rate contract structure is a direct
result of the requirements of PURPA itself.\556\ Concerns regarding the
alleged mismatch between avoided costs and the costs of renewable
technologies therefore are collateral attacks on the requirements of
PURPA itself, not our proposed implementation of it.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\554\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 43.
\555\ See Conf. Rep. at 97-98 (stating that the ``risk in
proceeding forward in the [QF] enterprise is not guaranteed to be
recoverable''); accord API, 461 U.S. at 416 (holding that QFs
``would retain an incentive to produce energy under the full-
avoided-cost rule so long as their marginal costs did not exceed the
full avoided cost of the purchasing utility'').
\556\ See Connecticut Authority Comments at 14 (``[C]ontracted
QF rates that take into account New England market conditions would
not deter lenders and investors. Many QFs have no fuel costs and low
variable costs of production; therefore, it is reasonable to find
that these QFs would earn substantial inframarginal rents on energy
sales. Further, QFs may be able to sell RECs and/or participate in
other Connecticut programs.'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
345. In the NOPR, the Commission noted the availability of various
hedging devices that would allow QFs to fix or limit the variability of
a variable avoided cost energy rate.\557\ We acknowledge those comments
explaining that hedging tools increase project expense and may not be
available to all QFs.\558\ However, the Commission never intended to
suggest that hedging is cost-free or that it would be appropriate for
all QFs. The commenters all agree that hedging is available for at
least some QFs.\559\ For such QFs, hedging can help provide energy rate
certainty if such certainty is required for financing. To the extent
that certainty is required, then the cost of hedging is a part of the
cost of financing the project that PURPA requires QFs to bear.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\557\ NOPR, 168 FERC ] 61,184 at P 72.
\558\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 45-46; Resources
for the Future Comments at 6-7; Solar Energy Industries Comments at
30.
\559\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
346. Public Interest Organizations cite testimony from the
Technical Conference stating that Southern Company has negotiated non-
QF renewable contracts with fixed energy rates rather than variable
energy rates.\560\ However, that testimony does not support the
contention that the Commission must provide for fixed avoided cost
energy rates for QF contracts and other LEOs. As the cited testimony
notes, Southern agreed to contracts with longer terms and with fixed
energy rates only because the
[[Page 54683]]
renewable energy developers agreed to a rate that was 50 to 60 percent
of the projected long-term avoided cost.\561\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\560\ Public Interest Organizations Comments at 33-34 (citing
NOPR, 168 FERC ] 61,184 at P 70 n.114 (citing Tech. Conference,
Docket No. AD16-16-000, Tr. 200 (filed June 30))).
\561\ Tech. Conference, Docket No. AD16-16-000, Tr. at 200
(filed June 30). The Commission notes that the PURPA Regulations
specifically permit QFs and utilities to agree to rates that differ
from what the PURPA Regulations require. 18 CFR 292.301(b). As the
testimony cited by the Public Interest Organizations suggests, QFs
that believe fixed energy avoided cost rates are required to obtain
financing are free to offer rate and/or other contractual
concessions in exchange for a fixed rate.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
347. Certain commenters expressed concern that, when a purchasing
electric utility is not avoiding the construction or purchase of
capacity as a consequence of entering into a contract with a QF, under
the NOPR's proposed rules a state could limit the QF's contract rate to
variable energy payments.\562\ However, in that event, the only costs
being avoided by the purchasing electric utility would be the
incremental costs of purchasing or producing energy at the time the
energy is delivered.\563\ Nothing in PURPA or the legislative history
of PURPA suggests that the Commission should set QF rates so as to
facilitate the financing of new QF capacity in locations where no new
capacity is needed.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\562\ CARE Comments at 4 n.7; EPSA Comments at 12.
\563\ See, e.g., City of Ketchikan, 94 FERC ] 61,293, at 62,061
(2001) (``[A]voided cost rates need not include the cost for
capacity in the event that the utility's demand (or need) for
capacity is zero. That is, when the demand for capacity is zero, the
cost for capacity may also be zero.'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
348. In the NOPR, the Commission also observed that the variable
avoided cost energy rate proposal might cause states to make other
changes to their administration of PURPA in ways that would improve the
financeability of QF projects. Most notably, states that had limited
the length of contract terms because of concerns about overpayments for
energy might be willing to allow longer term contracts if the contracts
have variable avoided cost energy rates. Longer term contracts with
fixed avoided cost capacity rates, in turn, would provide greater
revenue assurance to QFs.\564\ The comments submitted in response to
the NOPR support our analysis.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\564\ NOPR, 168 FERC ] 61,184 at P 65. Contrary to assertions by
some commenters, the Commission's conclusion in the NOPR about the
possible positive effects of the variable avoided cost energy rate
proposal was not based on speculation. See Public Interest
Organizations Comments at 36. Rather, the Commission relied on
testimony presented at the Technical Conference. See Technical
Conference Tr. at 142-43 (Idaho Commission) (``No matter the
starting point, allowing QFs to fix their avoided cost rates for
long terms results in rates which will eventually exceed and
overestimate avoided cost rates into the future. The longer the
term, the greater the disparity. . . . [The Idaho Commission]
recently reduced PURPA contract lengths to two years in order to
correct the disparity. We didn't reduce contract lengths to kill
PURPA. We did it to allow periodic adjustment of avoided cost
rates.'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
349. Further, there is some evidence that variable avoided cost
energy rates in contracts and LEOs could result in longer-term
contracts.\565\ To be clear, we are not finding that the variable
avoided cost energy rate provision in this final rule will necessarily
lead to longer term contracts and LEOs in every state, nor does our
decision to adopt this provision rely on such a finding.\566\ However,
the record supports the conclusion that the variable avoided cost
energy rate provision could lead to longer term contracts in at least
some states, and that likelihood provides support for the conclusion
that QFs will be able to obtain financing for their projects under this
provision if their costs are indeed below the purchasing utility's
avoided costs.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\565\ Idaho Commission Comments at 4 (allowing states to set
variable QF energy avoided costs ``would allow states to consider
longer term contracts without putting ratepayers at risk'') (citing
NOPR, 168 FERC ] 61,184 at 5 n.5).
\566\ We are not finding that variable avoided cost energy rates
would be appropriate only if they cause states to require longer
term contracts, and we are not adopting the suggestion made by
certain commenters that the Commission order states to require
longer contract terms. See NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at
47-48; Public Interest Organizations Comments at 6-7; sPower
Comments at 11.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
h. Other Claimed Benefits of Fixed Avoided Cost Energy Rates
i. Comments
350. Public Interest Organizations assert that maintaining the
requirement to pay QFs fixed rates serves as a hedge for consumers
because QFs, unlike utilities, bear their own risks and have provided
``billions of dollars'' in benefits to consumers. Public Interest
Organizations assert that eliminating QFs' rights to fixed rate
contracts ignores these benefits to consumers and puts them at
risk.\567\ Likewise, Solar Energy Industries portrays a fixed energy
rate as providing a hedge to a utility that the purchasing electric
utility may use as a revenue stream in connected markets. Solar Energy
Industries nevertheless argues that, in order to encourage QF
development, the Commission must ensure that QFs know the energy price
at the time of contracting and that utilities publish rates stating the
energy, capacity, and environmental attributes of the QF rate.\568\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\567\ Public Interest Organizations Comments at 45-46 (citing S.
Rep. No. 95-442, at 9, 22-23, 33 (1977), as reprinted in 1978
U.S.C.C.A.N. 7903, 7906, 7919-21, 7930; Public Interest
Organizations, Comments, Docket No. AD16-16-000, at 5, 19-21 (Oct.
17, 2018)). In earlier comments in Docket No. AD16-16-000, cited by
Public Interest Organizations in response to the NOPR, Public
Interest Organizations asserted that long-term fixed QF contracts
often act as a hedge that lowers QF financing expenses, which
benefits ratepayers, and insulates ratepayers from fuel price
fluctuations. Public Interest Organizations, Comments, Docket No.
AD16-16-000, at 20-21 (Oct. 17, 2018).
\568\ Solar Energy Industries Comments at 31-32.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
ii. Commission Determination
351. Fixed and variable energy rates each can provide benefits to
electric utility customers. These benefits are the converse of each
other: Variable avoided cost energy rates provide protection to
customers when energy costs decline, and fixed avoided cost energy
rates provide protection to customers when energy costs increase. By
giving the states the flexibility to choose either variable or fixed
avoided cost energy rates in QF contracts and LEOs, the Commission is
giving each state the ability to choose the protection that is best
suited for electric customers in their state, based on each state's
view of what the future may hold and the likelihood that variable
energy avoided costs will exceed fixed energy avoided costs during the
life of a QF contract or LEO.
352. We acknowledge that fixed avoided energy cost rates can serve
as a hedge against future fuel price increases in a way that protects
ratepayers, assuming such price increases actually occur. Given that
PURPA both places an avoided cost cap on QF rates, and requires that
such rates must be just and reasonable to the electric consumers of the
electric utility, we find it is appropriate to provide flexibility to
states to decide how to apportion such risks to their ratepayers in a
way that ensures QF avoided energy cost rates are consistent with
PURPA's requirements (i.e., by using either fixed or variable avoided
cost energy rates to best meet those requirements).
353. We caution, though, that having made that choice, a state is
not free to toggle a QF's contractual rate structure back and forth
unilaterally from one to the other as circumstances change; QFs are
entitled to the certainty that once a state has made its choice with
respect to a particular QF's contract or LEO, that QF's contract or LEO
is not subject to change during the term of that contract or LEO except
by mutual consent.
i. Potential Modifications to NOPR Proposal
i. Comments
354. The California Commission, Connecticut Authority, and
Massachusetts DPU support the variable energy rate proposal and suggest
that, in addition, states be given the discretion
[[Page 54684]]
to require the avoided capacity rate to vary.\569\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\569\ California Commission Comments at 27-28; Connecticut
Authority Comments at 14-15; Massachusetts DPU Comments at 8-10.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
355. In contrast, NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA urge the Commission,
if it allows variable energy rates, to adopt strict parameters for
setting capacity rates in order to provide some predictability to QFs
to allow them to obtain financing. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA
recommend that the Commission require forecasted capacity rates be
``offered in a long-term contract of at least 20 years after
commencement of sales under the agreement'' for ``[a]ll years during
the term of the QF's long-term contract after which the utility
forecasted to be capacity deficit in its load and resource balance, as
forecasted in its resource plan in effect at the time of the legally
enforceable obligation'' and ``[a]ny time the utility is planning or
undertaking actions to acquire a major generation resource or a major
capital investment at an aging facility at the time of creation of the
legally enforceable obligation.'' \570\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\570\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 51.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
356. Commissioner O'Donnell urges the Commission to provide
additional guidance to states on the minimum required contract duration
that would enable a QF to obtain financing from investors while
providing sufficient ratepayer protections.\571\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\571\ Commissioner O'Donnell Comments at 3.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
ii. Commission Determination
357. We decline to adopt the California Commission's, Connecticut
Authority's, and Massachusetts DPU's requests to permit a state to
require variable avoided cost capacity rates in addition to variable
avoided cost energy rates. There is a fundamental difference between
avoided energy costs and avoided capacity costs. Unlike avoided energy
costs, which fluctuate with changes in the variable cost of the
purchasing utility's marginal energy resource, a purchasing utility's
avoided capacity cost is determined at the time the utility incurs the
obligation to purchase capacity from a QF rather than self-build a
capacity resource or enter into a power purchase agreement with a third
party. Although a purchasing utility's avoided capacity cost may later
change as additional capacity acquisitions are avoided, the cost of the
capacity avoided by the purchasing utility as a consequence of
purchasing capacity from a particular QF at a particular moment in time
does not change.
358. As a simple illustrative example, if a utility is able to
avoid constructing a new generation facility with a capacity cost of
$10/MW-month as a result of purchasing power from a QF, its avoided
capacity cost is the $10/MW-month capacity cost that it would have been
incurred to construct the new facility. Once the utility commences its
purchases from the QF, it may not need additional capacity, and its
avoided capacity cost for the next QF would drop to $0/MW-month. It
would not be appropriate to then reduce the original QF's avoided
capacity charge to $0/MW-month, however, because the only reason that
the utility does not need additional capacity is because it already
purchased capacity from the original QF in order to avoid the $10/MW-
month capacity cost. That is, without the purchase from the original
QF, the utility would have incurred a capacity cost of $10/MW-month,
and that is the utility's avoided capacity cost for the term of its
contract with the original QF. It would be inappropriate, in other
words, for avoided cost capacity rates to change after they are first
set at the time a LEO (such as a contract) is established.
359. We also decline to adopt the suggestion of NIPPC, CREA, REC,
and OSEIA to adopt additional criteria for establishing avoided
capacity costs, including minimum contract lengths. We believe that the
existing rate-setting provisions adequately set out the criteria that
should be considered by a state in determining avoided capacity
costs.\572\ To the extent that any party believes a state has not
appropriately applied these criteria, that party has recourse to the
enforcement provisions of PURPA sections 210(g) and (h).\573\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\572\ See 18 CFR 292.304(e).
\573\ See also Policy Statement Regarding the Commission's
Enforcement Role Under Section 210 of the Public Utility Regulatory
Policies Act of 1978, 23 FERC ] 61,304.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
360. We decline to specify a minimum required contract length given
that it is up to states to decide appropriate contract lengths in a way
that accurately calculates avoided costs so as to meet all statutory
requirements.
8. Consideration of Competitive Solicitations To Determine Avoided
Costs
a. NOPR Proposal
361. The Commission in the NOPR proposed to revise the PURPA
Regulations in 18 CFR 292.304 to add subsection (b)(8). In combination
with new subsection (e)(1), this subsection would permit a state the
flexibility to set avoided cost energy and/or capacity rates using
competitive solicitations (i.e., requests for proposals or RFPs),
conducted pursuant to appropriate procedures.
362. The Commission recognized that one way to enable the industry
to move toward more competitive QF pricing is to allow states to
establish QF avoided cost rates through a competitive solicitation
process. The Commission previously has explored this issue. In 1988,
the Commission issued a notice of proposed rulemaking proposing to
adopt regulations that would allow bidding procedures to be used in
establishing rates for purchases from QFs.\574\ That rulemaking
proceeding, along with several related proceedings, ultimately was
withdrawn as overtaken by events in the industry.\575\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\574\ Regulations Governing Bidding Programs, FERC Stats. &
Regs. ] 32,455 (1988) (cross-referenced at 42 FERC ] 61,323)
(Bidding NOPR); see also Administrative Determination of Full
Avoided Costs, Sales of Power to Qualifying Facilities, and
Interconnection Facilities, FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 32,457 (1988)
(cross-referenced at 42 FERC ] 61,324) (ADFAC NOPR).
\575\ See Regulations Governing Bidding Programs, 64 FERC ]
61,364 at 63,491-92 (1993) (terminating Bidding NOPR proceeding);
see also Administrative Determination of Full Avoided Costs, Sales
of Power to Qualifying Facilities, and Interconnection Facilities,
84 FERC ] 61,265 (1998) (terminating ADFAC NOPR proceeding).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
363. Since then, the Commission held in a 2014 order addressing the
specific facts of the particular competitive solicitation at issue that
an electric utility's obligation to purchase power from a QF under a
LEO could not be curtailed based on a failure of the QF to win an only
occasionally-held competitive solicitation.\576\ In a separate
proceeding involving a different competitive solicitation, the
Commission declined to initiate an enforcement action where the state
competitive solicitation was an alternative to a PURPA program.\577\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\576\ See, e.g., Hydrodynamics, Inc., 146 FERC ] 61,193, at PP
31-35 (2014) (Hydrodynamics).
Competitive solicitation processes have been used more recently
in a number of states, including Georgia, North Carolina, and
Colorado. Georgia's competitive solicitation process is described at
Ga. Comp. R. & Regs. 515-3-4.04(3) (2018). North Carolina's
competitive solicitation process is described at 4 N.C. Admin. Code
11.R8-71 (2018). Colorado's competitive solicitation process is
described at sPower Development Co., LLC v. Colorado Pub. Utils.
Comm'n, 2018 WL 1014142 (D. Colo. Feb. 22, 2018).
\577\ Winding Creek Solar LLC, 151 FERC ] 61,103,
reconsideration denied, 153 FERC ] 61,027 (2015). But see Winding
Creek Solar LLC v. Peterman, 932 F.3d 861 (9th Cir. 2019).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
364. Given this precedent, the Commission proposed to amend its
regulations to clarify that a state could establish QF avoided cost
rates through an appropriate competitive solicitation process.
Consistent with its general approach of giving states flexibility in
the manner in which they determine
[[Page 54685]]
avoided costs, the Commission did not propose in the NOPR to prescribe
detailed criteria governing the use of competitive solicitations as
tools to determine rates to be paid to QFs, as well as to determine
other contract terms. The Commission stated that states arguably may be
in the best position to consider their particular local circumstances,
including questions of need, resulting economic impacts, amounts to be
purchased through auctions, and related issues.
365. Nevertheless, in considering what constitutes proper design
and administration of a competitive solicitation, the Commission found
it was appropriate to establish certain minimum criteria governing the
process by which competitive solicitations are to be conducted in order
for a competitive solicitation to be used to set QF rates. In that
regard, the Commission noted that it has addressed competitive
solicitations in prior orders in a number of contexts that provide
potential guidance to states and others. For example, the Commission's
policy for the establishment of negotiated rates for merchant
transmission projects,\578\ the Bidding NOPR, and the Hydrodynamics
case \579\ all suggest factors that could be considered in establishing
an appropriate competitive solicitation that is conducted in a
transparent and non-discriminatory manner.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\578\ Allocation of Capacity on New Merchant Transmission
Projects and New Cost-Based, Participant-Funded Transmission
Projects, 142 FERC ] 61,038 (2013).
\579\ See Hydrodynamics, 146 FERC ] 61,193 at P 32 n.70 (citing
Bidding NOPR, FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 32,455 at 32,030-42). The
Commission notes that, while QFs not awarded a contract pursuant to
an competitive solicitation would retain their existing PURPA right
to sell energy as available to the electric utility, if the state
has concluded that such QF capacity puts tendered after an
competitive solicitation was held are ``not needed,'' the capacity
rate may be zero because an electric utility is not required to pay
a capacity rate for such puts if they are not needed. See
Hydrodynamics, 146 FERC ] 61,193 at P 35 (referencing City of
Ketchikan, 94 FERC ] 61,293 at 62,061 (``[A]voided cost rates need
not include the cost for capacity in the event that the utility's
demand (or need) for capacity is zero. That is, when the demand for
capacity is zero, the cost for capacity may also be zero.'')).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
366. These factors, as proposed in the NOPR, include, among others:
(a) An open and transparent process; (b) solicitations should be open
to all sources to satisfy the purchasing electric utility's capacity
needs, taking into account the required operating characteristics of
the needed capacity; \580\ (c) solicitations conducted at regular
intervals; (d) oversight by an independent administrator; and (e)
certification as fulfilling the above criteria by the state regulatory
authority or nonregulated electric utility. The Commission proposed
that a state may use a competitive solicitation to set avoided cost
energy and capacity rates, provided that such competitive solicitation
process is conducted pursuant to procedures ensuring the solicitation
is transparent and non-discriminatory. The Commission proposed that
such a competitive solicitation must be conducted in a process that
includes, but is not limited to, the factors identified above which
would be set forth in proposed subsection (b)(8).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\580\ See 18 CFR 292.304(e); Windham Solar, 157 FERC ] 61,134 at
PP 5-6.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
367. In addition, the Commission sought comment on whether it
should provide further guidance on whether, and under what
circumstances, a competitive solicitation can be used as a utility's
exclusive vehicle for acquiring QF capacity.\581\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\581\ The Commission proposed that, even if a competitive
solicitation were used as an exclusive vehicle for an electric
utility to obtain QF capacity, QFs that do not receive an award in
the competitive solicitation would be entitled to sell energy to the
electric utility at an as-available avoided cost energy rate.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
b. Comments
i. Comments in Opposition
368. Several commenters oppose the NOPR proposal to allow states
the ability to set avoided cost energy and capacity rates through a
competitive solicitation such as an RFP.\582\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\582\ Allco Comments at 12; Blue Earth Comments at 1-2; Boulder
Comments at 6; CA Cogeneration Comments at 10-11; Green Power
Comments at 1-3; Industrial Energy Consumers Comments at 13.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
369. Allco states that allowing a state commission to use a
competitive solicitation price is simply giving another tool to a state
commission to eliminate QF projects.\583\ Allco also contends that this
proposal creates an apples and oranges scenario where a competitive
solicitation could be won by solar projects of 80 MWs at a low, steeply
discounted price that may never get built, resulting in a state
commission publishing that as an avoided cost for a 1 MW solar project
connected to the distribution system.\584\ Allco points to California's
Renewable Marketing Adjustment Tariff program as an example of a
competitive solicitation price failure.\585\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\583\ Allco Comments at 12.
\584\ Id.
\585\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
370. CA Cogeneration states that relying on a competitive
solicitation violates PURPA's mandatory purchase obligation, and the
regulations must always preserve the right of a QF to negotiate a
contract for the purchase of its output at an avoided cost rate.\586\
CA Cogeneration states that reliance on a competitive solicitation also
fails to provide the necessary financial and operational encouragement
for combined heat and power.\587\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\586\ CA Cogeneration Comments at 10.
\587\ Id. at 11.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
371. Covanta asserts that the Commission's proposed competitive
solicitation process would disadvantage technologies like Waste to
Energy that are not growing, or are closing facilities.\588\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\588\ Covanta Comments at 9.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
372. Southeast Public Interest Organizations argue that, in the
states that currently require some form of competitive solicitation,
many utilities do not regularly hold competitive solicitations, do not
make competitive solicitations open to all QFs, or do not provide QFs
the ability to sell to the utility outside of a competitive
solicitation process.\589\ Southeast Public Interest Organizations
maintain that the competitive solicitation process can be overly
burdensome and costly for smaller facilities. Southeast Public Interest
Organizations assert that no state requires, and no utility conducts, a
competitive solicitation to determine how best to meet the ongoing
energy needs that it currently meets through the operation of its
existing generation fleet and market purchases.\590\ In particular,
Southeast Public Interest Organizations represent that: (1) Florida
does not require an independent evaluator as part of its competitive
solicitation process; (2) Colorado and Oklahoma allow utilities to
apply for waivers of the competitive solicitation requirement; and (3)
North Carolina allows the incumbent utility to participate in the
competitive bidding process and to receive preferential treatment in
the form of waiving post bid security required for any independently
owned projects.\591\ Southeast Public Interest Organizations conclude
that, while a well-designed and well-implemented competitive
solicitation process could be an appropriate procurement and rate-
setting tool in some cases, competitive solicitations should never be
the only way to set rates or for QFs to sell their output, and close
consideration should be given to determinations of utility capacity
needs that could be manipulated to limit renewable energy
procurements.\592\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\589\ Southeast Public Interest Organizations Comments at 26.
\590\ Id. at 26-27.
\591\ Id. at 27.
\592\ Id. at 25-26.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
[[Page 54686]]
373. Mr. Mattson states that precedent and legislative intent
remove competitive solicitations from being a PPA option.\593\ Both Mr.
Mattson and Two Dot Wind point to the Commission's ruling in
Hydrodynamics that ``requiring a QF to win a competitive solicitation
as a condition to obtaining a long-term contract imposes an
unreasonable obstacle to obtaining a legally enforceable obligation.''
\594\ Two Dot Wind also states that competitive solicitations have not
worked in Montana, and that the NOPR's suggestion that competitive
bidding can replace PURPA is not supported by the factual record in
Montana.\595\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\593\ Mr. Mattson Comments at 23.
\594\ Id.; Two Dot Wind Comments at 10 (citing Hydrodynamics,
146 FERC ] 61,193).
\595\ Two Dot Wind Comments at 9-10.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
374. Industrial Energy Consumers expresses concern that the
parameters for competitive solicitations are not sufficiently developed
to ensure a well-structured, fairly administered, transparent, and non-
discriminatory process for procurement, and therefore opposes allowing
a competitive solicitation process to determine avoided costs at this
time.\596\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\596\ Industrial Energy Consumers Comments at 13.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
ii. Comments in Support
375. Several commenters support the NOPR proposal to allow states
the ability to set energy and capacity rates through a competitive
solicitation such as an RFP.\597\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\597\ Alaska Power Comments at 1; Distributed Sun Comments at 2;
EEI Comments at 32-33; El Paso Electric Comments at 4; NARUC
Comments at 3; NRECA Comments at 11; South Dakota Commission
Comments at 2-3.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
376. Multiple commenters, including EEI, NRECA, and the Oregon
Commission, support the notion that the states are in the best position
to tailor the competitive solicitation process to their needs, and that
the Commission should not provide detailed criteria governing the use
of competitive solicitations.\598\ EEI states that the fact that
competitive solicitations may be used to set avoided costs is an idea
nearly as old as PURPA.\599\ EEI also supports the Commission's
proposal for a state to allow a competitive solicitation to be used as
the exclusive vehicle for acquiring QF capacity.\600\ NRECA notes that
numerous NRECA members have already had success using competitive
solicitations to establish both energy and capacity rates in states
where competitive solicitations are permitted.\601\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\598\ EEI Comments at 32-33; NRECA Comments at 11; Oregon
Commission Comments at 3-4.
\599\ EEI Comments at 32.
\600\ Id. at 33.
\601\ NRECA Comments at 11.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
377. Growth and Opportunity Center states that competitive
solicitation processes, in place of avoided cost calculations, provide
better signals to investors of where their electricity is most valuable
because competitive solicitations reflect more informed estimates of
the real-time needs of electricity consumers. Growth and Opportunity
Center contends that the proposed rule changes, by giving states more
latitude to use competitive solicitations in complying with PURPA,
should result in prices for consumers that more accurately reflect
market costs for electricity.\602\ Growth and Opportunity Center also
asserts that in states using competitive solicitation processes,
nondiscrimination rules should be enforced to ensure that solicitations
are competitive and that no providers receive preferential
treatment.\603\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\602\ Growth and Opportunity Center Comments at 9.
\603\ Id. at 10.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
378. The Michigan Commission states that it recently approved using
competitive solicitations to determine avoided capacity costs for a
large electric utility in Michigan.\604\ The Michigan Commission states
that it believes that that recently approved structure aligns with the
Commission's proposal in the NOPR.\605\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\604\ Michigan Commission Comments at 4.
\605\ Id. at 5.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
379. Portland General asserts that, because the output of an
competitive solicitation represents a resource's true market costs, a
competitive solicitation is the correct method to determine avoided
cost.\606\ Portland General states that, given the competitive nature
of competitive solicitations, bidders are highly motivated, which
results in the procurement of resources with high benefit-to-cost
ratios. Portland General cites as an example its recent competitive
solicitation, which resulted in a $40.70-levelized price and reflects a
combination of technologies (wind, solar, and battery), whereas QFs,
which Portland General asserts provide lower capacity, are currently
offered at a $45.19 levelized price for solar energy.\607\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\606\ Portland General Comments at 11.
\607\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
380. Xcel urges the Commission's to give the states the option of
procuring all needed capacity through competitive bidding
processes.\608\ Xcel strongly believes that states must have the
ability to control capacity additions to ensure that customer needs and
state policy goals are met.\609\ Xcel explains that in many states,
including some in which the Xcel operating companies operate, resource
procurement is accomplished largely through state-administered IRP
processes, which are utilized to ensure a resource mix that meets the
overall public interest in affordable and clean energy. Xcel states
that these carefully calibrated processes can be upset when QFs bring
capacity on to a utility's system that does not align with the state's
vision of its optimal resource mix and when those QFs also attempt to
collect above-market payments from utilities and therefore customers.
Xcel states that Colorado's procurement efforts have been so successful
that in 2016 more than 400 bids for 238 distinct projects were
submitted for Public Service Company of Colorado alone, and that this
process resulted in some of the lowest prices for renewables seen as of
that date, with a median wind price of $19.30/MWh and a median solar
price of $30.96/MWh. Xcel argues that unsolicited puts by QFs, in
contrast, can impede the ability of states to meet their resource
planning goals and can undermine the competitive markets that states
like Colorado have already created or are striving to create.\610\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\608\ Xcel Comments at 10.
\609\ Id. at 8.
\610\ Id. at 9.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
381. North Carolina Commission Staff states that North Carolina has
implemented a competitive solicitation process for solar energy that
complements the PURPA reforms adopted by the state, with the first
solicitation concluding in April 2019.\611\ North Carolina Commission
Staff states that an independent administrator estimated the initial
nominal savings for the competitive solicitation with a 20-year
contract versus traditional avoided cost pricing to exceed $370 million
for the utilities involved.\612\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\611\ North Carolina Commission Staff Comments at 3-4.
\612\ Id. at 4.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
382. Duke Energy shares its state-specific experience with North
Carolina's competitive solicitation for renewable energy as a positive
example.\613\ Duke Energy states that Duke Energy Carolinas, LLC and
Duke Energy Progress, LLC recently completed their Tranche 1
Competitive Procurement of Renewable Energy RFP and procured
approximately 550 MW of new solar capacity for 20-year fixed price
contract terms at a projected savings of approximately $261 million
relative to administratively determined
[[Page 54687]]
forecasts of avoided costs over this same period.\614\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\613\ Duke Energy Comments at 10-12.
\614\ Id. at 12.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
iii. Comments Requesting Modifications/Clarifications
(a) Requests for Clarification and/or Separate Proceedings
383. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA argue that the NOPR fails to
explain (1) whether the Commission is proposing to merely clarify that
a state could use the lowest offer prices submitted in a competitive
solicitation to set the avoided costs of energy and capacity on a
prospective basis for any QF seeking a contract until the next
competitive solicitation, or (2) whether the Commission is proposing a
radical change in its precedent by revising its rules to provide that a
QF may only sell under a long-term contract if that QF wins a
competitive solicitation, which NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA assert
would be contrary to the Hydrodynamics \615\ and Winding Creek \616\
cases.\617\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\615\ Hydrodynamics, 146 FERC ] 61,193.
\616\ Winding Creek Solar LLC v. Peterman, 932 F.3d 861.
\617\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 62-63.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
384. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA request that any requirement to
win a competitive solicitation to obtain a long-term PURPA contract
should exempt small facilities.\618\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA
further state that the Commission should: (1) Require that the
competitive solicitation include no utility-ownership options; or (2)
if utility-owned generation may result, the competitive solicitation
must be: (i) Administered and scored (not just overseen) by a qualified
independent party, not the utility; (ii) any utility or utility-
affiliate ownership bid must be capped at its bid price and not allowed
traditional cost-plus ratemaking treatment; and (iii) the product
sought, minimum bidding criteria, and detailed scoring criteria must be
made known to all parties at the same time.\619\ Additionally, NIPPC,
CREA, REC, and OSEIA contend that an option for long-term contracts
should remain available for both small QFs and existing QFs outside of
a competitive solicitation.\620\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\618\ Id. at 67.
\619\ Id.
\620\ Id. at 67-68.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
385. The Michigan Commission states that it would welcome guidance
on whether, and under what circumstances, a competitive solicitation
can be used as a utility's exclusive vehicle for acquiring QF
capacity.\621\ Similarly, the Montana Commission recommends that the
Commission provide as much guidance to states as possible regarding the
requirements for transparency and non-discrimination.\622\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\621\ Michigan Commission Comments at 5.
\622\ Montana Commission Comments at 3.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
386. The California Commission states that the NOPR does not
provide states any more flexibility than they already have, and the
Commission's final order adopting revised regulations should clearly
state this.\623\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\623\ California Commission Comments at 23.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
387. Several commenters suggest that the Commission should conduct
focused additional processes on this topic.\624\ Advanced Energy
Economy suggests that the Commission conduct one or more workshops or
technical conferences, to explore in detail the specific factors that
would make a utility competitive solicitation process a truly
competitive process of a ``comparative quality'' to competitive
wholesale energy and capacity markets.\625\ Advanced Energy Economy
contends that such workshops or technical conferences could ultimately
be the basis for developing proposed regulations better guiding the
states and electric utilities in implementing open and competitive
solicitation processes to obtain relief from the mandatory purchase
obligation under PURPA section 210(m)(1)(C).\626\ Industrial Energy
Consumers argues that, if the Commission seeks to allow states to rely
on competitive solicitation processes, the Commission should undertake
a separate inquiry, with necessary technical conferences, to develop
specific parameters to govern such processes.\627\ If the Commission
relies directly on competitive solicitation processes in the final
rule, Industrial Energy Consumers states that if, after undertaking the
competitive solicitation, the utility rejects all offers and decides to
self-build, then the all-inclusive price of the self-build option
should at least establish the avoided cost rate for QFs seeking to
develop in that area.\628\ EPSA argues that the Commission should
require further proceedings, including another technical conference, to
discuss the protections that would be necessary in order to have a
genuinely level playing field for competitive solicitations.\629\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\624\ Advanced Energy Economy Comments at 13; EPSA Comments at
15-16; Industrial Energy Consumers Comments at 13-14.
\625\ Advanced Energy Economy Comments at 13.
\626\ Id.
\627\ Industrial Energy Consumers Comments at 13-14.
\628\ Id. at 14.
\629\ EPSA Comments at 16.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
388. Commissioner Slaughter states that PURPA sits at the
intersection of competition and regulatory policy in an area of vital
and urgent interest, and that the Commission should establish fair,
non-discriminatory guidelines for competitive solicitations that would
help states and other stakeholders maximize the benefits of competition
from low-cost energy sources, particularly utility-scale renewable
energy facilities.\630\ Commissioner Slaughter states that such
guidelines could form the basis for transitioning many local markets
from administratively determined prices to environments of dynamic
price discovery in which the rapidly decreasing cost of utility-scale
renewable energy can put maximum pressure on both new and pre-existing
fossil fuel-based sources of electricity.\631\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\630\ Commissioner Slaughter Comments at 1-2.
\631\ Id. at 3.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
389. EPSA states that the Commission should ensure that competitive
solicitations are properly designed to ensure that QFs have meaningful
opportunities to compete against resources owned by incumbent utilities
on a level playing field.\632\ EPSA states that the Commission should
use this opportunity to do a full assessment of how competitive
solicitations are working and could be enhanced, while providing
continued protections to prevent discrimination against QFs.\633\ EPSA
also emphasizes that, regardless of whatever competitive solicitation
rules the Commission ultimately adopts, the Commission must continue to
exercise its ``backstop'' oversight and enforcement authority to ensure
that any requirements are implemented in a consistent and appropriate
manner by individual states.\634\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\632\ EPSA Comments at 3.
\633\ Id. at 14.
\634\ Id. at 16-17.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
(b) Requests Regarding Proposed Criteria
390. Several commenters requested that the Commission clarify the
criteria that solicitations be conducted at regular intervals.\635\
Several commenters request that the Commission reconsider or remove
that criteria.\636\ sPower argues that the Commission should require
that such competitive solicitations be conducted at a minimum every two
years.\637\ Colorado Independent Energy
[[Page 54688]]
asserts that competitive solicitations should be held at regular
intervals to test the market, and that the Commission should consider
the entire market, not just projects 80 MW and under, in evaluating
whether there are full and competitive opportunities.\638\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\635\ APPA Comments at 17-18; Basin Comments at 9; Montana
Commission Comments at 3; sPower Comments at 9-10.
\636\ NorthWestern Comments at 7-8.
\637\ sPower Comments at 9-10.
\638\ Colorado Independent Energy Comments at 9-12.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
391. Several commenters oppose the requirement for an independent
administrator.\639\ APPA argues that the entire PURPA administrative
construct is designed to entrust to state regulatory authorities the
responsibility to carry out the duties they are assigned under the
Commission's regulations.\640\ NRECA believes that states are in the
best position to determine the need for ``oversight by an independent
administrator'' and recommends this criterion be deleted.\641\ NRECA
requests that, if the Commission retains the requirement that
competitive solicitation processes include some type of oversight,
instead of requiring oversight by an independent administrator, the
Commission should allow states the flexibility to allow electric
utilities to retain a third-party consultant for this purpose.\642\
NRECA contends that many cooperatives have long-standing relationships
with third-party consultants that assist the cooperatives in evaluating
power supply options, and requiring those cooperatives to now use some
other entity (i.e., the independent administrator) would be disruptive
and costly.\643\ Colorado Independent Energy notes that, while
independent evaluators are helpful, they are often employed by
utilities and thus sometimes reluctant to offer third party criticism
of the bid evaluation process.\644\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\639\ APPA Comments at 18; NRECA Comments at 11.
\640\ APPA Comments at 18 (citing 16 U.S.C. 824a-3(f) (expressly
calling for state regulatory authorities and nonregulated electric
utilities to implement Commission-issued PURPA regulations)).
\641\ NRECA Comments at 11.
\642\ Id. at 12.
\643\ Id.
\644\ Colorado Independent Energy Comments at 8.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
392. The Montana Commission requests clarification of the term
``independent administrator'' and ``certified'' as those terms are used
in the proposed revisions to Sec. 292.304(b).\645\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\645\ Montana Commission Comments at 3.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
393. sPower disagrees that a competitive solicitation should ``take
into account the required operating characteristics of the needed
capacity'' in order to produce accurate avoided cost rates and
recommends that a final rule remove that language from condition (ii)
in the Commission's list of conditions that a competitive solicitation
must meet.\646\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\646\ sPower Comments at 8.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
394. Colorado Independent Energy states that, in addition to the
guidelines provided in the NOPR, the Commission should include
additional guidelines, including that fairness of an ``all-source''
competitive solicitation must also be determined based on bid
evaluation and not just on a competitive solicitation. Colorado
Independent Energy asserts that competitive solicitation submissions
can be technology-specific, but not the evaluation or the analysis of
the need to be met by a competitive solicitation. Colorado Independent
Energy asserts that a true all-source selection process must allow
resource planning models to optimize among all bids received without
bias toward QF-eligible technologies such as renewable generation or
cogeneration.\647\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\647\ Colorado Independent Energy at 2.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
395. Several commenters stated that competitive solicitations must
be assessed using the criteria set forth in Allegheny.\648\ EPSA
further states that, while the Allegheny principles provide a good
starting point, additional protections will be required to level the
playing field between independent generators and utilities.\649\ R
Street asserts that, if an auction can meet the Allegheny standard,
then generators in that state would not be eligible for QF
designations. R Street suggests that QFs should not be able to force
their power on utilities if they lose such fairly administered
auctions.\650\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\648\ EPSA Comments at 14-15 (citing Allegheny, 108 FERC ]
61,082); R Street Comments at 3-4; Solar Energy Industries
Supplemental Comments, Docket No. AD16-16-000, at 32-37 (filed Aug.
28, 2019).
\649\ EPSA Comments at 15.
\650\ R Street Comments at 3-4.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
396. Solar Energy Industries asserts that the Commission should
require a purchasing electric utility to provide the state commission,
and make available for public inspection, a post-solicitation report
that: (1) Identifies the winning bidders; (2) includes a copy of any
reports issued by the independent evaluator; and (3) demonstrates that
the solicitation program was implemented without undue preference for
the interests of the purchasing utility or its affiliates. Solar Energy
Industries further assert that the solicitation program should include
clear details regarding the manner in which the bids will be scored and
clearly specify price and non-price criteria under which bids are
evaluated including: (1) Acceptable delivery points and any scoring
deductions for delivery to other points; (2) credit evaluation criteria
and development securing requirements; and (3) performance
requirements.\651\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\651\ Solar Energy Industries Supplemental Comments, Docket No.
AD16-16-000, at 21 (filed August 28, 2019).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
397. Public Interest Organizations argue that the Commission's
proposal does not require that state competitive solicitation
procedures meet the statutory floor established through PURPA that
rates both (1) encourage small power producers and (2) not discriminate
relative to the utility's own generation and other non-QF
generators.\652\ To ensure competitive solicitations actually meet the
statutory criteria, the Commission must ensure that competitive
solicitations meet four minimum standards.\653\ First, Public Interest
Organizations state that solicitations must account for utility-owned
and non-QF generation and cannot be a limited competition between QFs
without the ability to displace non-QF generation.\654\ As an example
of an incorrectly-conducted, and unlawfully-discriminatory, bidding
process, Public Interest Organizations cite the Nevada competitive
solicitation process that is limited to QFs to meet a small, segregated
portion of the utility's energy and unmet capacity requirements.\655\
Second, to ensure that QFs receive the same price that other generation
receives, Public Interest Organizations state that all sources of
supply must compete in the competitive solicitation-- including the
utility's own generation.\656\ Third, Public Interest Organizations
state that the solicitation process cannot be used in any way to
curtail or delay a utility's obligation to purchase from QFs.\657\
Fourth, the ``required operating characteristics of the needed
capacity'' factor suggested in the NOPR cannot be used as a surrogate
to define characteristics of only non-QF generation or to allow a
utility to pick among favored generators.\658\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\652\ Public Interest Organizations Comments at 69-70.
\653\ Id. at 70.
\654\ Id.
\655\ Id. at 71-72.
\656\ Id. at 72.
\657\ Id. at 72-73.
\658\ Id. at 73.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
398. Biogas states that, if QFs are to enter into competitive
solicitations as a vehicle for PURPA, then there must be some
correcting for the inequitable tax and regulatory provisions afforded
to incumbent utilities and select renewable
[[Page 54689]]
technologies, in order to ensure a fair market opportunity.\659\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\659\ Biogas Comments at 2.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
399. American Dams requests that QFs competing against a utility
that can rate base the cost of new generation should be entitled to
similar valuation provided that QF costs are at or less than those of
the utility.\660\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\660\ American Dams Comments at 3.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
(c) Other Requests
400. In their comments to the NOPR, Solar Energy Industries
reference their August 28, 2019 comments in Docket No. AD16-16-
000,\661\ in which they describe the ``SEIA Counterproposal.'' That
document proposes that, where a utility seeks to meet identified
capacity needs through an open, fairly designed, and independently
administered competitive solicitation: (i) The purchasing electric
utility would only have to pay QFs for capacity to the extent that the
purchasing electric utility failed to meet identified need through the
competitive solicitation; and (ii) the QF would be paid for its output
(energy and capacity) at the market rate established through the
competitive solicitation process.\662\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\661\ Solar Energy Industries Supplemental Comments, Docket No.
AD16-16-000, at 17-40 (filed Aug. 28, 2019).
\662\ Solar Energy Industries Comments at 38.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
401. Solar Energy Industries request that the Commission supplement
proposed 18 CFR 292.304(b)(5) to require that: (1) Participants are
provided with complete and transparent information regarding
transmission constraints, levels of congestion, and interconnections;
and (2) the solicitation is linked with the purchasing utility's IRP
and is conducted for the entirety of a utility's anticipated capacity
needs.\663\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\663\ Id. at 39.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
402. Solar Energy Industries request that the Commission expressly
implement safeguards to prevent utility self-dealing and affiliate
abuse, with regard to both price and non-price terms.\664\ Solar Energy
Industries reference their previous comments in this proceeding, which
they state describe practices of PacifiCorp,\665\ NorthWestern,\666\
Duke,\667\ and Xcel \668\ purportedly showing that these utilities have
attempted to reduce QFs' ability to sell while simultaneously seeking
to build and rate base their own substantial renewable resources.\669\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\664\ Id.
\665\ Solar Energy Industries Supplemental Comments, Docket No.
AD16-16-000, at 25-28 (filed August 28, 2019).
\666\ Id. at 28-29.
\667\ Id. at 29-31.
\668\ Id. at 21.
\669\ Solar Energy Industries Comments at 40.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
403. ELCON states that it continues to see shortcomings in
competitive procurement practices across regions.\670\ A current
example ELCON provides is Dominion Energy Virginia's 2019 RFP which,
ELCON argues, limited competition in a manner that all but guarantees
that a Dominion self-build option will prevail because it restricts
participation to new resources only and does not permit an independent
third party to evaluate bids.\671\ Another example ELCON provides is a
recent Entergy Louisiana solicitation through which a natural gas
generating facility was approved despite opposition from Louisiana
industrial consumers who argued that the competitive solicitation was
improperly designed to limit resource options to new construction
comparable to a self-build.\672\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\670\ ELCON Comments at 27.
\671\ Id.
\672\ Id. at 28.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
404. ELCON asserts that, to be competitive, a competitive
solicitation must be transparent, face independent oversight, have
safeguards against affiliate abuse involving transactions between
franchised utilities and their market-based affiliates, and have well-
defined technical parameters.\673\ ELCON states that experiences with
competitive solicitations thus far expose the challenges of achieving a
workably competitive process. ELCON urges the Commission to set a high
bar, with enforcement to verify that a process is sufficiently
competitive.\674\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\673\ Id. at 28-29.
\674\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
405. NorthWestern states that it supports the Commission's proposal
to use competitive solicitations or RFPs to establish avoided capacity
costs, but not avoided energy costs, because NorthWestern believes that
an energy-only competitive solicitation has no relation to the market
whereas a capacity competitive solicitation does.\675\ NorthWestern
believes that use of a competitive solicitation should be the preferred
vehicle for setting avoided capacity rates for QFs because this will
ensure that the capacity is acquired at the least cost thereby
benefiting customers.\676\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\675\ NorthWestern Comments at 7.
\676\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
406. Institute for Energy Research states that it would go even
further than the NOPR proposal and require that competitive
solicitations be the default whenever possible, with states having to
justify case-by-case why a non-competitive solicitation is needed,
because solicitation is the best expression of the Congressional
mandate to encourage competition.\677\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\677\ Institute for Energy Research Comments at 1.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
407. Harvard Electricity Law states that the NOPR's proposed 18 CFR
292.304(b)(8)(ii), requiring solicitations must be open to ``all
sources''--could be read as inconsistent with the Commission's CPUC
orders \678\ and the 2019 CARE v. CPUC decision.\679\ Harvard
Electricity Law argues that, if the Commission amends its avoided cost
rules to allow states to set avoided cost rates based on competitive
solicitations, it should clarify that states may set tiered rates, as
the Commission and the U.S. Court of Appeals for the Ninth Circuit has
allowed in the above cases.\680\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\678\ Cal. Pub. Utils. Comm'n, 133 FERC ] 61,059, clarification
and reh'g denied, 133 FERC ] 61,059 (2010), reh'g denied, 134 FERC ]
61,044 (2011) (CPUC) .
\679\ Californians for Renewable Energy v. Cal. Pub. Utils.
Comm'n, 922 F.3d 929, 937 (9th Cir. 2019) (CARE v. CPUC) (holding
that ``where a state has [a renewable portfolio standard (RPS)] and
the utility is using a QF's energy to meet the RPS, the utility
cannot calculate avoided costs based on energy sources that would
not also meet the RPS[,]'' which ``comports with PURPA's goal to put
QFs on an equal footing with other energy providers'').
\680\ Harvard Electricity Law Comments at 31.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
408. The Oregon Commission recommends that the Commission emphasize
the need for states to have adequate safeguards to protect bidders'
confidential and commercially sensitive proprietary information when
using competitive solicitations to determine or inform avoided cost
rates.\681\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\681\ Oregon Commission Comments at 4.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
409. sPower states that the issue of using a competitive
solicitation process to establish avoided cost rates has sometimes been
conflated with using a competitive solicitation process to establish a
LEO, and sPower encourages the Commission to continue to analyze these
distinct issues separately.\682\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\682\ sPower Comments at 3.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
410. Resources for the Future stresses that competitive
solicitations alone would minimize QF costs but would not establish
avoided cost rates, which depend on much more than the cost of QF
generation.\683\ However, used in concert with forward curves,
Resources for the Future states that competitive solicitations could
provide an effective complementary method.\684\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\683\ Resources for the Future Comments at 8-9.
\684\ Id. at 9.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
c. Commission Determination
411. In this final rule, we affirm the NOPR proposal to revise the
PURPA Regulations to explicitly permit a state the flexibility to set
avoided energy and/or capacity rates using competitive solicitations
(i.e., RFPs), conducted
[[Page 54690]]
pursuant to appropriate procedures in a transparent and non-
discriminatory manner. A primary feature of a transparent and non-
discriminatory competitive solicitation is that a utility's capacity
needs are open for bidding to all capacity providers, including QF and
non-QF resources, on a level playing field. This level playing field
ensures that any QF's capacity rates that result from the competitive
solicitation are just and reasonable and non-discriminatory avoided
cost rates.
412. Consistent with our general approach of giving states
flexibility in the manner in which they determine avoided costs, we do
not prescribe detailed criteria governing the use of competitive
solicitations as tools to determine rates to be paid to QFs, as well as
to determine other contract terms. States arguably are in the best
position to consider their particular local circumstances, including
questions of need, resulting economic impacts, amounts to be purchased
through auctions, and related issues.
413. In considering what constitutes proper design and
administration of a competitive solicitation, however, we find it
appropriate to establish certain minimum criteria governing the process
by which competitive solicitations are to be conducted in order for an
competitive solicitation to be used to set QF rates. These factors,
which we proposed in the NOPR and adopt here, include, among others:
(a) An open and transparent process; (b) solicitations should be open
to all sources to satisfy that purchasing electric utility's capacity
needs, taking into account the required operating characteristics of
the needed capacity; (c) solicitations conducted at regular intervals;
(d) oversight by an independent administrator; and (e) certification as
fulfilling the above criteria by the state regulatory authority or
nonregulated electric utility.
414. We affirm that such competitive solicitations must be
conducted in a process that includes, but is not limited to, the
factors identified above that will be set forth in 18 CFR
292.304(b)(8). This rule does not undo any competitive solicitations
conducted prior to the effective date of this final rule that may not
have met these criteria. This rule applies only to competitive
solicitations conducted after the effective date of the final rule. We
also provide modifications and clarifications to the NOPR proposal, as
described below.
i. Requests for Clarification and/or Separate Proceedings
415. As an initial matter, in the NOPR, the Commission addressed
competitive solicitations in two related but distinct contexts. The
first, to be discussed in this section, relates to the proposal to
explicitly permit a state the flexibility to set avoided cost energy
and/or capacity rates using competitive solicitations (i.e., RFPs),
conducted pursuant to appropriate procedures. The second, to be
discussed below, in section IV.G.2 of this final rule, concerns the
NARUC proposal that urged the Commission to give meaning to PURPA
section 210m(1)(C) by establishing a ``yardstick'' by which a
vertically integrated utility outside of an RTO or ISO could apply to
terminate the mandatory purchase obligation if it conducts sufficiently
competitive RFPs for energy or capacity.
416. More generally, we support the use of competitive
solicitations as a means to foster competition in the procurement of
generation and to encourage the development of QFs in a way that most
accurately reflects a purchasing utility's avoided costs. We believe
that allowing QFs to compete to provide capacity and energy needs,
through a properly administered competitive solicitation, may help
ensure an accurate determination of the purchasing electric utility's
avoided cost, and therefore result in prices meeting the PURPA's
statutory requirements. We also believe that it is reasonable for
states to choose to require QFs to be responsive to price signals as to
where and when capacity is needed.
We believe that a properly administered competitive solicitation
can help provide such price signals.
417. Furthermore, we believe that competitive solicitations may be
an especially appropriate tool for developing competition in the
markets outside of RTOs and ISOs, where there are no organized
competitive markets in place where QFs can make sales.
418. We emphasize, however, that neither the Commission's current
regulations, nor those adopted in this final rule, require a state or a
purchasing electric utility to use a competitive solicitation to
determine avoided cost rates for QFs. Consistent with other changes in
our regulations discussed above, we give states the flexibility to use
a properly structured competitive solicitation for this purpose, but we
do not mandate that they do so.
419. Furthermore, in light of the substantial experience the
industry has with competitive solicitations within and outside of the
PURPA context, and the voluminous comments the Commission has received
regarding competitive solicitations, we find that there is not
currently a need for a separate proceeding or additional procedures to
address competitive solicitation issues, such as holding workshops or
technical conferences. Should further procedures appear beneficial in
light of actual competitive solicitation experience under PURPA and the
regulations adopted today, such a proceeding may be appropriate in the
future.
ii. Proposed Criteria
420. We continue to find that competitive solicitations as
discussed in this final rule may accurately reflect a purchasing
electric utility's avoided costs and ensure that the resulting rates
for winners of such competitive solicitations are consistent with
PURPA. A competitive solicitation may more accurately value QF capacity
over time by subjecting it to competition with other sources. Such
competitive solicitations may provide more certainty both to QFs
regarding when and how often they will be eligible to compete and to
purchasing utilities regarding how they may expect to fulfill their
capacity needs.
421. The Commission clarifies that, if a utility acquires all of
its capacity through properly conducted competitive solicitations
(using the factors described above), and does not add capacity through
self-building and purchasing power from other sources outside of such
solicitations, the competitive solicitations could be the exclusive
vehicle for the purchasing electric utility to pay avoided capacity
costs from a QF. In this situation, using properly conducted
competitive solicitations as the exclusive vehicle to determine the
purchasing electric utility's avoided cost capacity rates would allow
QFs a chance to compete to provide the utility's capacity needs on a
level playing field with the utility. We clarify that it is up to the
states to determine whether to require that a utility's total planned
self-build and power purchase options must compete in the competitive
solicitations, and we will not direct such a requirement here.
422. If a state decides to require utility self-build and power
purchase options to participate in competitive solicitations, then a QF
that does not obtain an award in a competitive solicitation would have
no right to an avoided cost capacity rate more than zero because the
utility's full capacity needs would have been met by the competitive
solicitation.\685\ However,
[[Page 54691]]
QFs would continue to have the right to put energy to the utility at
the as-available avoided cost energy rate because the purchasing
utility will still be able to avoid incurring the cost of generating
energy even when it does not need new capacity.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\685\ This would be consistent with City of Ketchikan, 94 FERC
at 62,061 (``[A]voided cost rates need not include the cost for
capacity in the event that the utility's demand (or need) for
capacity is zero. That is, when the demand for capacity is zero, the
cost for capacity may also be zero.'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
423. If the state does not require utility self-build and purchase
options to participate in competitive solicitations, then QFs that lose
in a competitive solicitation still may have the right to avoided cost
capacity rates more than zero if the state determines that the utility
still has capacity needs after the competitive solicitation that
otherwise could be met through the utility's self-build or purchase
options.
424. The Commission has held and we reaffirm here that, when
capacity is not needed, the avoided capacity cost rate can be
zero.\686\ Competitive solicitations conducted pursuant to the rules
adopted in this final rule that are held whenever capacity is needed
provide QFs a level playing field on which to compete to sell capacity.
This approach further shields purchasing electric utilities from
situations like those explained by Xcel, where QFs could simply sit out
the competitive solicitation process (or participate but not have their
bids accepted), but then seek to sell capacity to the purchasing
electric utility and to receive a separate higher administratively-
determined avoided cost rate including an avoided cost capacity rate,
and even potentially displace non-QF competitive solicitation
winners.\687\ This approach benefits ratepayers because allowing QFs to
compete in properly conducted, competitive solicitations that are held
whenever capacity is needed allows the purchasing utility to obtain
needed capacity efficiently. To be clear, the competitive solicitation
is not to be a means to determine a QF's right to put as-available
energy to the utility. But the competitive solicitation can be the
means to determine what, if any, rate the QF will be paid for capacity.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\686\ Id. at 62,061 (``[A]voided cost rates need not include the
cost for capacity in the event that the utility's demand (or need)
for capacity is zero. That is, when the demand for capacity is zero,
the cost for capacity may also be zero.'').
\687\ See Xcel Comments at 2-3, 9-10.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
425. Multiple commenters point out that using competitive
solicitations could be a beneficial way to carry out the Congressional
intent behind PURPA. However, many of these same commenters claim that
the competitive solicitations carried out to date do not live up to
this standard. In other words, commenters assert that the competitive
solicitations conducted to date have often not been properly conducted
and instead have been unfair. As described above, assertions about
specific states' competitive solicitation processes include that:
--The competitive solicitations conducted in Florida are unfair because
they do not require an Independent Evaluator as part of the competitive
solicitation process; \688\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\688\ Southeast Public Interest Organizations Comments at 27.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
--the competitive solicitations conducted in Colorado and Oklahoma are
unfair because purchasing electric utilities are allowed to apply for
waivers of the competitive solicitation requirement; \689\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\689\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
--The competitive solicitations conducted in North Carolina are unfair
because the incumbent purchasing electric utility can receive
preferential treatment in the form of waivers of the post bid security
otherwise required for any independently owned projects; \690\ and
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\690\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
--The competitive solicitations conducted in Nevada are unfair because
the process is limited to QFs to meet a small, segregated portion of
the utility's energy and unmet capacity requirements.\691\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\691\ Public Interest Organizations Comments at 71-72.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
426. Commenters also make assertions about unfair practices of
purchasing electric utilities, including that the purchasing electric
utilities have attempted to reduce QFs' ability to sell while the
purchasing electric utilities are simultaneously seeking to build and
rate base their own substantial renewable resources.
427. The criteria proposed in the NOPR were aimed at ensuring that
competitive solicitations are conducted fairly. In this final rule, the
Commission finds that, in order to use the results of a competitive
solicitation to set avoided cost rates, the competitive solicitation
must be conducted in a transparent and non-discriminatory manner. Such
a competitive solicitation must be conducted in a process that
includes, but is not limited to, the following factors: (i) The
solicitation process is an open and transparent process that includes,
but is not limited to, providing equally to all potential bidders
substantial and meaningful information regarding transmission
constraints, levels of congestion, and interconnections, subject to
appropriate confidentiality safeguards; (ii) solicitations must be open
to all sources, to satisfy that purchasing electric utility's capacity
needs, taking into account the required operating characteristics of
the needed capacity; (iii) solicitations are conducted at regular
intervals; (iv) solicitations are subject to oversight by an
independent administrator; and (v) solicitations are certified as
fulfilling the above criteria by the relevant state regulatory
authority or nonregulated electric utility through a post-solicitation
report.
428. Without judging the competitive solicitations conducted to
date, we find that henceforth any competitive solicitation that does
not comply with these factors will be viewed as not transparent and
discriminatory, and not a basis for either setting the avoided cost
capacity rate that a QF may charge the purchasing electric utility or
limiting which generators can receive a capacity rate. Phrased
differently, we will presume that any future competitive solicitation
that does not comply with the factors adopted in this final rule does
not comply with the Commission's regulations implementing PURPA.
429. In addition, to further promote fairness, the Commission makes
several clarifications, as described below.
430. We clarify that competitive solicitations must also be
conducted in accordance with the Allegheny principles under which the
Commission evaluates a competitive solicitation: (1) Transparency, a
requirement that the solicitation process be open and fair; (2)
definition, a requirement that the product, or products, sought through
the competitive solicitation be precisely defined; (3) evaluation, a
requirement that the evaluation criteria be standardized and applied
equally to all bids and bidders; and (4) oversight, a requirement that
an independent third party design the solicitation, administer bidding,
and evaluate bids prior to selection.\692\ While the NOPR's proposed
guidelines for competitive solicitations were generally inclusive of
the Allegheny principles, in order to more precisely define what is and
what is not a properly conducted competitive solicitation that can be
used to determine what generators will be entitled to an avoided cost
capacity rate, and what that rate will be, we specifically clarify here
that the Allegheny principles apply as well.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\692\ Allegheny, 108 FERC ] 61,082 at P 18.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
431. We also revise the proposed language in 18 CFR
292.304(d)(8)(i) to clarify that participants must be provided with
substantial and meaningful information regarding transmission
constraints, levels of congestion, and interconnections, subject to
appropriate confidentiality
[[Page 54692]]
safeguards. We believe that it is important that all participants in
the competitive solicitation have access to these data as a necessary
predicate for a nondiscriminatory competitive solicitation process, and
we find that requiring that this information be provided will help
ensure that a competitive solicitation is open and transparent. We
acknowledge the risk that competitive solicitation participants could
use this information to gain a competitive advantage that could be used
outside of the competitive solicitation, but find that this risk can be
minimized through the use of non-disclosure agreements and placing
reasonable limits on those persons permitted to review the information,
just as is done in other Commission proceedings where this issue
arises.
432. We also clarify that the requirement that the competitive
solicitation process be open and transparent includes that the electric
utility provide the state commission, and make available for public
inspection, a post-solicitation report that: (1) Identifies the winning
bidders; (2) includes a copy of any reports issued by the independent
evaluator; and (3) demonstrates that the solicitation program was
implemented without undue preference for the interests of the
purchasing utility or its affiliates. We find this consistent with the
requirement that competitive solicitations be open and transparent, to
not only ensure that utilities are not discriminating against QFs, but
also to help all stakeholders and the public at large better understand
the utility's competitive solicitation processes and thus to be
confident in the fairness of the process and of the results.
433. Regarding the requirement that solicitations must be open to
all sources to satisfy the purchasing electric utility's capacity
needs, taking into account the required operating characteristics of
the needed capacity, we decline to remove the phrase ``taking into
account the operating characteristics of the needed capacity.'' There
may be times when a utility needs capacity with specific attributes,
such as specific ramping capability, that cannot be filled by certain
types of generators. However, we agree with Public Interest
Organizations that this phrase may not be used to define
characteristics of only non-QF generation or to allow a utility to
select favored generators.\693\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\693\ Public Interest Organizations Comments at 73.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
434. We decline to be overly prescriptive as to what constitutes
``regular intervals.'' In general, utilities should be reviewing their
capacity needs frequently, and the state or nonregulated electric
utility is in the best position to determine the frequency of that
review. However, there may be times when a utility's review of capacity
needs reveals that no capacity is needed, and it would not make sense
for a competitive solicitation to be mandated at such a time.
435. We similarly decline to be overly prescriptive as to what
constitutes an ``independent administrator.'' Commenters argue on both
sides whether the NOPR proposal goes too far or not far enough. On the
one hand, NRECA argues that states are in the best position to
determine the need for oversight by an independent administrator and
recommends this criterion be deleted.\694\ On the other hand, Colorado
Independent Energy notes that independent administrators are often
employed by utilities and thus sometimes reluctant to offer third party
criticism of the bid evaluation process.\695\ We clarify that the
independent administrator, who is responsible for administering the
competitive solicitation, must be an entity independent from the
purchasing electric utility in order to help ensure fairness. Whether
the entity is called an independent administrator or a third-party
consultant, the substantive requirement of this factor is that the
competitive solicitation not be administered by the purchasing electric
utility itself or its affiliates, but rather by a separate, unbiased,
and unaffiliated entity not subject to being influenced by the
purchasing utility. We recognize, however, that such an independent
administrator will need to be selected and paid. Though we are not
directing a process, we note that the selection and payment could be
done under the auspices of a state regulatory authority or by mutual
agreement between the utility and the competitive solicitation
participants.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\694\ NRECA Comments at 11. In this final rule, we note, for
ease of readability we have used the word ``state'' to refer to both
state regulatory authorities and to nonregulated electric utilities.
Thus, in the context of nonregulated electric utilities in
particular, to say that the ``state'' can fairly administer the
competitive solicitation is to say that the nonregulated electric
utility can, essentially, be both the purchasing electric utility
and potentially the independent administrator of its own competitive
solicitation. That is a result we cannot countenance.
\695\ Colorado Independent Energy Comments at 8.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
436. In response to the Montana Commission's request for
clarification as to what ``certified'' means within the guideline that
requires certification of the competitive solicitation by the state
regulatory authority or nonregulated electric utility as fulfilling the
above criteria, we clarify that, after a thorough review of the
competitive solicitation procedures used and the competitive
solicitation results, certification of the competitive solicitation
requires a written, formally-issued finding by the state that the
competitive solicitation and its results comply with PURPA and this
Commission's PURPA regulations--and must include the independent
administrator's report to the same effect.
437. We decline at this time to add any additional requirements for
competitive solicitations. We continue to believe that states may be in
the best position to consider their particular local circumstances. We
think that the guidelines adopted here, in conjunction with the
Allegheny principles and other clarifications made here, provide an
adequate framework for competitive solicitations to be conducted
efficiently, transparently and in a nondiscriminatory manner.
438. We also clarify that, if a competitive solicitation is not
conducted fairly and in accordance with the guidelines here, then an
aggrieved entity may challenge the state's competitive solicitation in
the appropriate forum, which could include any one or more of the
following: (1) Initiating or participating in proceedings before the
relevant state commission or governing body; (2) filing for judicial
review of any state regulatory proceeding in state court (under PURPA
section 210(g)); or, alternatively (3) filing a petition for
enforcement against the state at the Commission and, if the Commission
declines to act, later filing a petition against the state in U.S.
district court (under PURPA section 210(h)(2)(B)).
iii. Other Requests
439. We decline to grant Solar Energy Industries request to require
that solicitations be linked with the purchasing electric utility's
IRP. Where a state has an IRP,\696\ it may make sense to link the
competitive solicitation processes with the IRP so that the competitive
solicitation is conducted for the entirety of a utility's anticipated
capacity needs. On the other hand, IRPs may come in a variety of forms.
For example, an IRP may merely be a general projection of short- and
long-term load growth and potential resources to meet such growth, and
each generation project may be subject to specific approval based on
actual specific need. In order to provide states flexibility in
conducting these
[[Page 54693]]
processes, we will not require such links between competitive
solicitations and IRPs, although such links certainly are permitted if
a state deems it to be appropriate.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\696\ 16 U.S.C. 2621(a), (d)(7) (requiring states to consider
whether to employ integrated resource planning).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
440. Regarding facilities not designed primarily to sell
electricity to the purchasing electric utility, such as waste to power
small power production facilities and cogeneration facilities, we find
that an exemption from competitive solicitation processes is
unnecessary. We do not exempt small power production facilities from
the competitive solicitation process; we are not persuaded that such an
exemption is appropriate given that exempting large classes of small
power producers could frustrate the price discovery function of the
competitive solicitation. A large number of exempted small facilities
could disrupt the competitive solicitation process. We clarify,
however, that QFs whose capacity is 100 kW or less already are entitled
to standard rates regardless of whether they compete in a competitive
solicitation and we do not change that regulation in this final
rule.\697\ Given that we view competitive solicitations as an important
price discovery tool and that states already are required to establish
standard rates for such entities, there is no need to determine prices
for QFs at 100 kW or less through a competitive solicitation.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\697\ See 18 CFR 292.304(c).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
441. The Commission clarifies that any competitive solicitation
conducted may not force alteration of existing QF contracts. A QF
receiving a capacity payment is entitled to that payment for the
duration of the term of its contract, and a competitive solicitation is
necessarily forward looking based on the results of that auction.
C. Relief From Purchase Obligation in Competitive Retail Markets
1. NOPR Proposal
442. The Commission in the NOPR proposed to add regulatory text at
the end of Sec. 292.303(a) of the PURPA Regulations to provide that a
utility's purchase obligation may be reduced to the extent the
purchasing electric utility's supply obligation has been reduced by a
state retail choice program. The Commission stated that it was
reasonable for electric utilities' PURPA capacity purchase obligations
to be reduced to the extent retail choice reduces their supply
obligations. To the extent Provider of Last Resort (POLR) supplies are
obtained through solicitations having a particular contract term such
as one year, the Commission proposed that the length of the utility's
PURPA purchase contract should match the term of the POLR supply
solicitation contracts in order to more accurately reflect the
utility's avoided costs.
443. The Commission proposed, through this change, to provide that
state regulatory authorities and nonregulated electric utilities have
flexibility to respond to the possibility that, over time, a utility's
POLR supply obligation may decrease (or increase). The Commission
intended that this proposal would apply prospectively from the
effective date of a final rule and would not disturb contracts in
effect at the time the utility's supply obligation is reduced.
2. Comments
444. APPA, DTE Electric, EEI, Institute for Energy Research,
NorthWestern, NRECA, Pennsylvania Commission, Portland General, and We
Stand for Energy filed comments in support of the Commission's proposal
to provide that the purchase obligation may be reduced to the extent
the purchasing electric utility's supply obligation has been reduced by
a state retail choice program.\698\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\698\ APPA Comments at 20; DTE Electric Comments at 4-5; EEI
Comments at 41-42; Institute for Energy Research Comments at 1-2;
NorthWestern Comments at 8; NRECA Comments at 13-14; Pennsylvania
Commission Comments at 6-7; Portland General Comments at 12-13; and
We Stand Comments at 1.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
445. New England Small Hydro, NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA, and
Public Interest Organizations filed opposing comments arguing that the
Commission lacks the statutory authority to implement this proposal
because the Commission lacks discretion to reduce an electric utility's
mandatory purchase obligation except through PURPA section 210(m).\699\
New England Small Hydro claims that PURPA section 210(a) clearly states
that electric utilities must purchase the electric energy from QFs, and
that the Commission does not have the authority to deviate from the
statute.\700\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA argues that the Commission's
existing regulations adequately address the concern at issue because
any reduction in the long-term capacity needs of the utility due to
retail access should be reflected in avoided capacity rates offered to
QFs.\701\ Public Interest Organizations claim that the Commission
proposes to remove state authority by requiring QF contracts with a
POLR to match the term of the POLR's other supply contracts.\702\
Public Interest Organizations also state that even if the Commission
had such authority, there is no evidence in the record to support
matching QF contract lengths with a POLR's other supply contracts.
Public Interest Organizations also assert that the Commission's
proposal unlawfully discriminates against QFs to the extent that it
fails to treat QF contracts in parity with any of a POLR's other supply
contracts.\703\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\699\ New England Small Hydro Comments at 15-16; NIPPC, CREA,
REC, and OSEIA Comments at 68-69; and Public Interest Organizations
Comments at 74-75.
\700\ New England Small Hydro at 16 (citing Chevron U.S.A., Inc.
v. Nat. Res. Def. Council, 467 U.S. 837 (1984)).
\701\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 69.
\702\ Public Interest Organizations Comments at 74.
\703\ Id. at 75.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
446. Biogas and Covanta argue that the rationale for this proposal
is unclear and that the NOPR fails to justify the reduction of a
utility's obligation to purchase QF power based on the amount of any
non-utility generator's supply into the utility's service
territory.\704\ Covanta states that the NOPR incorrectly concludes that
all public power is renewable power.\705\ Biogas and Covanta assert
that the existence of a competitive retail market does not mean there
is a competitive retail market for biogas or waste-to-energy QFs.\706\
Biogas and Covanta also argue that the NOPR would reduce that already
limited market by providing greater leverage to the purchasing electric
utility, and urge the Commission to remove barriers to local government
options for energy purchase rates.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\704\ Biogas Comments at 2; Covanta Comments at 9.
\705\ Covanta Comments at 9.
\706\ Biogas Comments at 2; Covanta Comments at 9-10.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
447. Ohio Commission Energy Advocate states that under Ohio law, an
electric distribution utility is required to provide consumers within
its certified territory a standard service offer of all competitive
retail electric services necessary to maintain essential electric
services to customers, including a firm supply of electric generation
services.\707\ Ohio Commission Energy Advocate claims that all PUCO-
regulated electric distribution utilities satisfy this obligation
through competitive solicitation for default service within the context
of an electric security plan.\708\ Ohio Commission Energy Advocate
believes that the electric distribution utility should retain the full
purchase obligation because the regulated utility maintains the
obligation to serve as the POLR for all
[[Page 54694]]
``wires-connected'' customers.\709\ Ohio Commission Energy Advocate
also states that it is concerned by the lack of alternatives to the
mandatory purchase obligation and would question any interpretation of
PURPA that contemplates a scenario where no entity has a purchase
obligation for a QF.\710\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\707\ Ohio Commission Energy Advocate Comments at 5.
\708\ Id. at 6.
\709\ Id. at 6-7.
\710\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
448. ELCON, California Utilities, Chamber of Commerce, Connecticut
Authority, and Michigan Commission request further clarification on how
the Commission's proposal will be implemented. ELCON states that
industrial customers conditionally support the reduction in obligation
to purchase based on a state retail choice program, subject to the
development of clear and enforceable criteria that exclude mandatory
purchase obligation relief for default supply obligations that
utilities meet with their own generation.\711\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\711\ ELCON Comments at 19.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Similarly, California Utilities state that because of the various
ways states have developed restructured retail markets, the Commission
should provide additional guidance as to the various ways that state
commissions can address load reductions due to retail choice while
protecting legacy utilities.\712\ California Utilities explain that
they need Commission guidance to ensure that cost recovery for past and
future mandated QF purchases is equitable to the remaining retail
customers in the legacy utilities' distribution service areas and that
future PURPA mandates or costs are fairly allocated consistent with
cost-causation principles.\713\ Chamber of Commerce states that the
Commission should clarify that the reduction in a utility's QF purchase
obligation is measured against the amount of a utility's load that has
elected an alternative supplier, as opposed to eligible load.\714\
Chamber of Commerce claims that in certain states, only a portion of an
electric utility's load is eligible to select an alternative
electricity supplier and that such percentage would serve as the limit
for any corresponding reduction in a utility's QF purchase obligation.
Michigan Commission states that its retail choice program caps retail
choice at 10 percent of an electric utility's retail customer demand,
and seeks clarification on (1) whether the reduction in a utility's
purchase obligation would equal the reduction in its supply obligation,
be based on the percentage of its customer demand participating in the
state's retail choice program, or some other metric; and (2) how
fluctuations in the state's retail choice program and resulting
purchase obligation should be addressed.\715\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\712\ California Utilities Comments at 5.
\713\ Id. at 7.
\714\ Chamber of Commerce Comments at 5.
\715\ Michigan Commission Comments at 5-6.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
449. Connecticut Authority supports the proposal to modify
distribution utilities' must-purchase obligations.\716\ Connecticut
Authority states that since Connecticut's electric industry
restructuring, distribution utilities' purchases of QF output have not
been used to serve retail customers, rather the distribution utility
acts as an intermediary selling output into the New England markets.
Connecticut Authority asserts that the Commission should clarify that
the state regulatory authority is responsible for determining the
appropriate adjustment to the distribution utility's must-purchase
obligation and providing notice of such determination to the
Commission.\717\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\716\ Connecticut Authority Comments at 16.
\717\ Id. at 17.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
450. Connecticut Authority claims that QF output is different from,
and cannot be substituted in for, distribution utility-provided default
standard or last resort services. Connecticut Authority explains that
standard service is procured in six-month tranches, last resort service
is procured in three-month tranches, and that distribution utilities do
not self-manage their default service supply portfolios.\718\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\718\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
451. Connecticut Authority states that while it agrees that
matching the contract terms for default service supply and QF supply
could potentially reduce the burden of over-estimated avoided costs and
give states flexibility to respond quickly to changes to a distribution
utility's default supply obligation, the Commission should not mandate
any term length for the mandatory purchase obligation.\719\ Instead,
Connecticut Authority asserts that the Commission should allow the
state to establish the term based on state-specific circumstances.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\719\ Id. at 18.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
452. California Utilities request that the Commission reaffirm that
all alternative retail suppliers, including Electric Service Providers
(ESP) and Community Choice Aggregators (CCA), are electric utilities
subject to the PURPA purchase obligation.\720\ California Utilities
explain that ESPs and CCAs are the two types of entities that
California allows to sell power to retail customers in the distribution
service territories of CPUC-regulated utilities, and argues that such
entities meet the definition of electric utility used in PURPA.\721\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\720\ California Utilities at 9.
\721\ Id. at 9-10.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
453. California Utilities state that the Commission should clarify
that a state has no authority to exempt any traditional or alternative
retail supplier from the PURPA mandatory purchase obligation in order
to ensure QFs that there is a robust market to sell their energy and
capacity to entities that actually serve load in the event a legacy
utility is relieved of all or part of its PURPA obligations.\722\
California Utilities also state that the Commission should clarify that
alternative retail suppliers must make avoided cost information
publicly available to allow QFs to locate and identify potential buyers
that may have higher avoided costs than legacy utilities that have lost
load and may no longer have capacity needs.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\722\ Id. at 11.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
454. California Utilities argue that for states such as California
that allow alternative retail suppliers to opt out of procuring
capacity and require legacy utilities to provide capacity on their
behalf, it would be unfair for legacy utilities to pay a QF any amount
for energy greater than the LMP unless the price differential for which
the legacy utility can sell the energy in the market is paid for by the
alternative retail supplier that was short on capacity.\723\ California
Utilities explain that this would prevent cost shifts to customers who
remain with the legacy utility such that all costs associated with the
mandatory PURPA purchases made by the legacy utility on behalf of the
alternative retail supplier would be borne by customers of the
alternative retail supplier.\724\ California Utilities also argue that
the Commission should clarify that if legacy utilities are required to
procure capacity from QFs on behalf of alternative retail suppliers,
states must require alternative retail suppliers to pay for such QF
purchases at the avoided cost rate set by the state for the legacy
utility for capacity.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\723\ Id. at 12.
\724\ Id. at 13.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
455. California Utilities urge the Commission to adopt a stranded
cost regulation addressing PURPA obligations incurred by legacy
utilities that lose load to retail competition consistent with the cost
recovery guarantee in PURPA section 210(m)(7)(A).\725\ California
Utilities argue that such regulation should be clear that prudently
incurred costs include any costs associated with a
[[Page 54695]]
purchase under a state-mandated contract. California Utilities propose
new language to Sec. 292.304(g) regarding implementation of the cost
recovery mandate in section 210(m)(7)(A) of PURPA stating, in part,
that ``[a] state commission may not find any costs associated with any
legally enforceable obligation that it has imposed on an electric
utility imprudent.'' \726\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\725\ Id. at 14.
\726\ Id. at 15.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
3. Commission Determination
456. In this final rule, we decline to adopt the proposed
regulation permitting states with retail competition to allow relief
from the purchase obligation. We instead clarify that the Commission's
existing PURPA Regulations already require that states, to the extent
practicable, must account for reduced loads in setting QF rates.
457. Specifically, 18 CFR 292.304(e)(3) already does and will
continue to allow states, when setting avoided cost rates, to take into
account ``the ability of the electric utility to avoid costs, including
the deferral of capacity additions.'' We regard this existing
regulation as allowing a state to consider reductions in a purchasing
electric utility's supply obligations given retail competition and the
purchasing electric utility's POLR obligations under state law. We
further clarify that this clarification is not intended to be reflected
as a MW-for-MW reduction (or increase) based on yearly changes in load
and therefore does not and may not serve to terminate a purchasing
utility's mandatory purchase obligation under PURPA section
210(a).\727\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\727\ 18 CFR 292.304(e)(3).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
D. Evaluation of Whether QFs Are at Separate Sites
1. Rebuttable Presumption of Separate Sites
a. NOPR Proposal
458. The Commission proposed to allow entities challenging a QF
certification to rebut the presumption that affiliated facilities
located more than one mile apart are considered to be separate QFs. The
Commission proposed that this change would be effective as of the date
of the final rule, which means that such challenges could only be made
to QF certifications and recertifications that are submitted after the
effective date of the final rule in this proceeding.
459. The Commission proposed that an entity can seek to rebut the
presumption only for those facilities that are located more than one
mile apart and less than 10 miles apart. The Commission believed that,
just as there are some facilities that may be so close that it is
reasonable to irrebuttably treat them as a single facility (those a
mile or less apart), so there are some facilities that are sufficiently
far apart that it is reasonable to treat them as irrebuttably separate
facilities.\728\ That latter distance, the Commission believed, is 10
miles or more apart. Thus, if two affiliated facilities are one mile or
less apart, they would continue to be irrebuttably presumed to be a
single facility at a single site. If affiliated facilities are 10 miles
or more apart, they would be irrebuttably presumed to be separate
facilities at separate sites.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\728\ NOPR, 168 FERC ] 61,184 at P 101. As discussed in detail
in section IV.D.1.d below, this final rule will change the
references to ``separate facilities'' or ``the same facility'' to
``at separate sites'' or ``at the same site.''
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
460. The Commission proposed that if affiliated facilities are more
than one mile apart and less than 10 miles apart, there would still be
a presumption, but it would be a rebuttable presumption, that they are
separate facilities at separate sites. Purchasing electric utilities
and others thus would be able to file a protest attempting to rebut the
presumption for facilities more than one mile apart and less than 10
miles apart and argue that they should be treated as a single facility.
The Commission could also act sua sponte. The Commission proposed that
self-certifications will remain effective after a protest has been
filed, until such time as the Commission issues an order revoking the
certification.
461. The Commission proposed allowing an entity seeking QF status
to provide further information in its certification (both self-
certification and application for Commission certification), to
preemptively defend against rebuttal by asserting factors that
affirmatively show that the affiliated facilities are indeed separate
facilities at separate sites.\729\ Anyone challenging the QF
certification would be allowed to assert factors to show that the
facilities are actually part of the same, single facility.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\729\ While a QF with a net power production capacity of 1 MW or
less is not required to formally certify its QF status (either
through a self-certification or application for Commission
certification), if the QF's status is later challenged (i.e., by a
petition for declaratory order), the QF would be able to respond by
affirmatively demonstrating that its facilities are not located at
the same site as other affiliated facilities and thus that the QF
does not exceed the 80 MW size limitation.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
462. The Commission proposed limiting protests challenging QF
status by requiring any entity filing a protest to specify facts that
make a prima facie demonstration that the facility described in the
self-certification, self-recertification, or Commission certification
does not satisfy the requirements for QF status. General allegations or
unsupported assertions would not be a basis for denial of
certification. The Commission further proposed limiting protests to QF
status by requiring that once the Commission has affirmatively
certified an applicant's QF status through either a Commission
certification proceeding or in response to protests challenging QF
status, any later protest to a QF's existing certification asserting
that facilities further than one mile apart are part of a single QF
must demonstrate changed circumstances that call into question the
continued validity of the earlier certification.
463. The Commission proposed that physical and ownership factors
may be asserted to rebut or defend against rebuttal. Noting that no
single factor would be dispositive, the Commission proposed the
following factors: (1) Physical characteristics including such common
characteristics as: infrastructure, property ownership, interconnection
agreements, control facilities, access and easements, interconnection
facilities up to the point of interconnection to the distribution or
transmission system, collector systems or facilities, points of
interconnection, motive force or fuel source, off-take arrangements,
property leases, and connections to the electrical grid; and (2)
ownership/other characteristics, including such characteristics as
whether the facilities in question are: Owned or controlled by the same
person(s) or affiliated persons(s), operated and maintained by the same
or affiliated entity(ies), selling to the same electric utility, using
common debt or equity financing, constructed by the same entity within
12 months, managing a power sales agreement executed within 12 months
of a similar and affiliated facility in the same location, placed into
service within 12 months of an affiliated project's commercial
operation date as specified in the power sales agreement, or sharing
engineering or procurement contracts. The Commission solicited comments
on whether the Commission should rely on some or any of these factors,
or other factors, or whether the various factors should be considered
together and weighed.
464. The Commission stated that it will continue to rely on its
definition of ``affiliate'' provided in 18 CFR 35.36(a)(9), and noted
that subsection (iii) provides that the Commission may determine, after
appropriate notice and
[[Page 54696]]
opportunity for hearing, that a person stands in such relation to a
specified company that there is likely to be an absence of arm's-length
bargaining in transactions between them as to make it necessary or
appropriate in the public interest or for the protection of investors
or consumers that the person be treated as an affiliate.\730\ The
Commission intended, when applying its rules on separate facilities, to
consider this provision of its regulations, when entities otherwise
would not be deemed affiliates under the other provisions of the
definition, to determine whether a person nevertheless should be
treated as an affiliate. In doing so, the Commission stated that it
could take into consideration many of the same factors that would
reasonably be considered in evaluating whether facilities located over
one and less than 10 miles apart are a single facility or separate
facilities.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\730\ 18 CFR 35.36(a)(9)(iii).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
465. The Commission believed that this change, together with the
proposed definition of ``electrical generating equipment'' and revision
to the FERC Form No. 556, would more closely align with Congress's
requirement that QFs seeking to certify as small power production
facilities are in fact below the 80 MW statutory limit for such
facilities.\731\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\731\ See 16 U.S.C. 796(17)(A)(ii) (defining small power
production facility as, inter alia, ``a facility which is an
eligible solar, wind, waste, or geothermal facility, or a facility
which--. . . has a power production capacity which, together with
any other facilities located at the same site (as determined by the
Commission), is not greater than 80 megawatts'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
b. Commission Determination
466. As further discussed and revised in the following sections, we
adopt the NOPR proposal. Henceforth, if a small power production
facility seeking QF status is located one mile or less from any
affiliated small power production QFs that use the same energy
resource, it will be irrebuttably presumed to be at the same site as
those affiliated small power production QFs. If a small power
production facility seeking QF status is located ten miles or more from
any affiliated small power production QFs that use the same energy
resource, it will be irrebuttably presumed to be at a separate site
from those affiliated small power production QFs. If a small power
production facility seeking QF status is located more than one mile but
less than ten miles from any affiliated small power production QFs that
use the same energy resource, it will be rebuttably presumed to be at a
separate site from those affiliated small power production QFs.
467. We adopt the proposal to allow a small power production
facility seeking QF status to provide further information in its
certification (both self-certification and application for Commission
certification) or recertification (both self-certification and
application for Commission recertification), to preemptively defend
against anticipated challenges by identifying factors that
affirmatively show that its facility is indeed at a separate site from
affiliated small power production QFs that use the same energy resource
and that are more than one but less than 10 miles from its facility. We
will correspondingly allow any interested person or entity to challenge
a QF certification (both self-certification and application for
Commission certification) or recertification (both self-recertification
or application for Commission recertification) that makes substantive
changes to the existing certification as further described below).\732\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\732\ We note that a protester must separately file for
intervention seeking to be made a party to the proceeding; the
filing of a protest does not make that person or entity a party. 18
CFR 385.102(c), 385.211(a)(2).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
468. As explained in section IV.D.1.f below, we adopt the NOPR's
proposed factors, with certain additions.
469. We adopt the proposal to clarify that challenges to QF status
require that the interested person or entity filing a protest must
specify facts that make a prima facie demonstration that the facility
described in the certification (both self-certification and application
for Commission certification) or recertification (both self-
recertification and application for Commission recertification) does
not satisfy the requirements for QF status. Additionally, any protest
must be adequately supported, with supporting documents, contracts, or
affidavits, as appropriate. General allegations or unsupported
assertions will not provide a basis for denial of certification or
recertification. We additionally limit protests, as described more
fully in section IV.E below, by clarifying that protests may be made to
an initial certification (both self-certification and application for
Commission certification) filed on or after the effective date of this
final rule, but only to a recertification (both self-recertification
and application for Commission recertification) filed on or after the
effective date of this final rule that makes substantive changes to the
existing certification. We adopt the proposal to limit protests by
requiring that once the Commission has affirmatively certified an
applicant's QF status in response to a protest opposing a self-
certification or self-recertification, or in response to an application
for Commission certification or recertification, any later protest to a
recertification (self-recertification or application for Commission
recertification) making substantive changes to a QF's existing
certification must demonstrate changed circumstances from the facts on
which the Commission acted on the certification filing that call into
question the continued validity of the earlier certification.\733\
Finally, the Commission retains the discretion to summarily reject
protests where a protest reiterates arguments already made against the
same QF that the Commission previously denied or otherwise rejected.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\733\ An interested person or entity can choose to file a
petition for declaratory order, with fee, at any time (that is, not
only within 30 days from the date of the filing of the Form No.
556). However, if the Commission has affirmatively certified an
applicant's QF status in response to a protest opposing a self-
certification or self-recertification, or in response to an
application for Commission certification or recertification, any
later petition for declaratory order protesting the QFs existing
certification must demonstrate changed circumstances from the time
the Commission acted on the certification that call into question
the continued validity of the earlier certification.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
c. Need for Reform
i. Comments
470. Multiple parties have expressed concern that some QF
developers of small power production facilities are circumventing the
one-mile rule, and thereby circumventing PURPA, by strategically siting
small power production facilities that use the same energy resource
slightly more than one mile apart in order to qualify as separate small
power production facilities.\734\ Several commenters state that the
NOPR-proposed changes will reduce the opportunity for gaming.\735\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\734\ See APPA Comments at 21; Center for Growth and Opportunity
Comments at 5-6; Consumers Energy Comments at 4; East River Comments
at 1-2; EEI Comments at 43; ELCON Comments at 35; Governor of Idaho
Comments at 1; Idaho Commission Comments at 5-7; Idaho Power
Comments at 13; Missouri River Energy Comments at 5; Mr. Moore
Comments at 2; Northern Laramie Range Alliance Comments at 2;
NorthWestern Comments at 9; NRECA Comments at 14-15; Portland
General Comments at 14.
\735\ APPA Comments at 21; Center for Growth and Opportunity
Comments at 5-6; Consumers Energy Comments at 4; East River Comments
at 1-2; EEI Comments at 43; ELCON Comments at 35; Governor of Idaho
Comments at 1; Idaho Commission Comments at 5-7; Idaho Power
Comments at 13; Missouri River Energy Comments at 5; Mr. Moore
Comments at 2; Northern Laramie Range Alliance Comments at 2;
NorthWestern Comments at 12; NRECA Comments at 14-15; Portland
General Comments at 14.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
471. Several commenters argue, to the contrary, that there is no
evidence of
[[Page 54697]]
gaming of the current one-mile rule.\736\ Con Edison argues that
utilities are not overwhelmed with QFs using the one-mile rule and
there is little to no evidence to the contrary.\737\ sPower states that
it is difficult to see how developers that comply with this clear
bright-line rule could be said to be circumventing.\738\ New England
Small Hydro argues that the Commission is attempting to address
perceived abuses of the 80 MW limitation by burdening projects that do
not abuse the system.\739\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\736\ Solar Energy Industries Comments at 51; Southeast Public
Interest Organizations Comments at 31; SC Solar Alliance Comments at
19.
\737\ Con Edison Comments at 5.
\738\ sPower Comments at 5.
\739\ New England Small Hydro Comments at 17.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
ii. Commission Determination
472. The record shows that, since the establishment of the one-mile
rule in the PURPA Regulations in 1980, the development of large numbers
of affiliated renewable resource facilities, requires a revision of the
one mile-rule. We find that the final rule will reduce the opportunity
for developers of small power production facilities to circumvent the
current one-mile rule by strategically siting small power production
facilities that use the same energy resource slightly more than one
mile apart.\740\ While such circumvention may not be an everyday
occurrence, we agree with commenters that the record demonstrates it is
still a sufficient possibility under the current regulations that the
Commission is justified in addressing it in order to comply with the
statute.\741\ The final rule, as adopted, still retains the presumption
that small power production QFs more than one mile apart are located at
separate sites, but simply makes the presumption rebuttable for small
power production QFs located more than one mile but less than 10 miles
apart, allowing the Commission the ability to address those
circumstances.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\740\ The regulation, in practice, is only of consequence if the
facilities located ``at the same site'' would exceed a power
production capacity of 80 MW, as that is the size limit for a small
power production facility to qualify as a QF. 16 U.S.C.
796(17)(A)(ii).
\741\ See APPA Comments at 21; Center for Growth and Opportunity
Comments at 5-6; Consumers Energy Comments at 4; East River Comments
at 1-2; EEI Comments at 43; ELCON Comments at 35; Governor of Idaho
Comments at 1; Idaho Commission Comments at 5-7; Idaho Power
Comments at 13; Missouri River Energy Comments at 5; Mr. Moore
Comments at 2; Northern Laramie Range Alliance Comments at 2;
NorthWestern Comments at 9; NRECA Comments at 14-15; Portland
General Comments at 14.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
d. Site Definition
i. Comments
473. Solar Energy Industries state that, in El Dorado County Water
Agency, the Commission found that ``the critical test under PURPA
relates to whether the facilities are located at one site rather than
whether they are integrated as a project.'' \742\ Solar Energy
Industries argue that the proposed rule, as drafted, abandons the focus
on whether the facilities are located at one site and transforms it
into an analysis as to whether affiliated QFs are part of the same
project. Solar Energy Industries similarly contend that it is arbitrary
to change from a ``same site'' to an ``integrated project''
standard.\743\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\742\ Solar Energy Industries Comments at 60 (quoting El Dorado
Cty. Water Agency, 24 FERC ] 61,280, at 61,578 (1983)).
\743\ Id. at 61-62.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
474. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA state that the existing rule is a
reasonable means of implementing the statutory phrase ``same site,''
particularly given the statutory directive to encourage QF development,
and state that they prefer the current bright line rule.\744\ Allco
argues that the proposed rule is divorced from the statutory use of
``site.'' Allco asserts that the Commission lacks authority to define
the term ``site'' in a manner other than one reasonably related to its
ordinary meaning and argues that the Commission's definition of site
arbitrarily limits QF development for no apparent reason.\745\ The DC
Commission would like the Commission to leave the resolution of certain
disputes over whether QFs are separate to state commissions.\746\ Idaho
also requests that states be given as much discretion as possible.\747\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\744\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 70.
\745\ Allco Comments at 16.
\746\ DC Commission Comments at 9.
\747\ Idaho Comments at 1.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
475. EEI states that the interpretation of ``same site'' is
determined by the Commission, and that there is nothing in the statute
that prevents the Commission from modifying its interpretation of the
term ``same site.'' \748\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\748\ EEI Comments at 42.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
ii. Commission Determination
476. We modify the NOPR proposal to change terminology relating to
the determination of whether small power production facilities are
separate facilities to focus not on whether they are separate
facilities, but rather to mirror the statutory language and thus focus
on whether they are at ``the same site.'' In that regard, we change
references to ``separate facilities'' or ``the same facility'' to ``at
separate sites'' or ``at the same site.''
477. The NOPR refers to determining whether affiliated facilities
are ``separate facilities'' or ``a single facility.'' However, both the
statute and the existing regulations contemplate that the Commission
will determine what is ``the same site,'' \749\ and do not require the
Commission to determine whether two facilities are a single facility.
The statute defines a small power production facility as an eligible
facility, which, together with other facilities located at the same
site (as determined by the Commission), has a power production capacity
no greater than 80 MW,\750\ and the Commission's regulations have long
approached the matter as defining how to determine ``the same site.''
\751\ We find that the Commission's determination of whether or not a
small power production facility is a QF (i.e., exceeds a power
production capacity of 80 MW) should continue to be focused on whether
the small power production facility seeking QF status and other nearby
affiliated small power production QFs are at the same site or at
separate sites.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\749\ 16 U.S.C. 796(17)(A)(i); 18 CFR 292.204(a).
\750\ 16 U.S.C. 796(17)(A)(i).
\751\ 18 CFR 292.204(a).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
478. We also modify the NOPR proposal to change the irrebuttable
and rebuttable presumptions regarding affiliated facilities to instead
apply to affiliated small power production qualifying facilities. As
noted, the NOPR refers to determining whether affiliated facilities are
``separate facilities'' or ``a single facility.'' We find that only
affiliated small power production QFs are relevant to the determination
of whether the small power production facility seeking QF status and
other nearby facilities are at the same site or separate sites.\752\
Correspondingly, as further detailed below, we will allow entities
challenging a QF certification (both self-certification and application
for Commission certification) or recertification (both self-
recertification and application for Commission recertification) to
rebut the presumption that a small power production facility seeking QF
status is at a separate site from any affiliated small power production
QFs that use the same energy resource and that are located
[[Page 54698]]
more than one but less than 10 miles from it.\753\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\752\ We note, however, that, in the context of a PURPA section
210(m) proceeding, all affiliates are relevant in evaluating whether
a QF has nondiscriminatory access to a competitive market.
\753\ Though not at issue here, we also note that the facilities
need to use the same energy resource. 18 CFR 292.204(a)(1).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
479. We therefore modify the language proposed in the NOPR. In sum,
we find that if a small power production facility seeking QF status is
located one mile or less from any affiliated small power production QFs
that use the same energy resource, it will be irrebuttably presumed to
be ``at the same site'' as those affiliated small power production QFs
(rather than a single facility at a single site, as proposed in the
NOPR). The Commission finds that if a small power production facility
seeking QF status is located ten miles or more from any affiliated
small power production QFs that use the same energy resource, it will
be irrebuttably presumed to be at a separate site from those affiliated
small power production QFs (rather than separate facilities at separate
sites, as proposed by the NOPR). We find that if a small power
production facility seeking QF status is located more than one but less
than ten miles from any affiliated small power production QFs that use
the same energy resource, it will be rebuttably presumed to be at a
separate site from those affiliated small power production QFs (rather
than separate facilities at separate sites, as proposed in the NOPR).
480. Purchasing electric utilities and others will be able to file
a protest and identify factors attempting to rebut the presumption for
a small power production facility seeking QF status that has an
affiliated small power production QF that uses the same energy resource
more than one but less than 10 miles from it, and argue that the small
power production facility seeking QFs status should be treated as ``at
the same site'' as the affiliated small power production QF located
more than one but less than 10 miles from it (rather than as a single
facility, as proposed in the NOPR). We will allow a small power
production facility seeking QF status to provide further information in
its certification (both self-certification and application for
Commission certification) or recertification (both self-recertification
and application for Commission recertification) to preemptively defend
against rebuttal by identifying factors that affirmatively show that
its facility is indeed at a separate site from an affiliated small
power production QF located more than one but less than 10 miles from
it (rather than separate facilities at separate sites, as proposed in
the NOPR).
481. Regarding the requests to allow states to decide whether
affiliated small power production QFs are located at separate sites, we
note that, in PURPA section 201, now codified in section 3 (17) of the
FPA, Congress authorized the Commission to determine whether the
applicant and other facilities are located at the same site. This
Commission will therefore continue to make these determinations.
e. Distance Between Facilities
i. Comments
482. Several commenters contend that the proposal to institute a
rebuttable presumption for facilities that are more than one mile but
less than 10 miles apart is arbitrary and lacks sufficient supporting
evidence.\754\ ELCON notes that the choice of 10 miles as the threshold
is not supported by any evidence.\755\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\754\ Allco Comments at 16; Ares Comments at 7; Borrego Solar
Comments at 4; ELCON Comments at 19; Public Interest Organizations
Comments at 93; SC Solar Alliance Comments at 17; Solar Energy
Industries Comments at 60, 62.
\755\ ELCON Comments at 35-36.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
483. Regarding the proposed rebuttable presumption for QFs more
than one but less than 10 miles apart, Terna Energy argues that the
NOPR effectively increases the ``exclusion zone'' around a QF's
electrical generating equipment from approximately three square miles
(3.1415 square miles, the circle with one-mile radius around the QF's
electrical generating equipment, assuming a point generating source) to
over 300 square miles (i.e. a 10-mile radius circle), a 100-times
increase to the ``exclusion area'' for a single QF.\756\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\756\ Terna Energy Comments at 4.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
484. New England Small Hydro notes that hydroelectric generators
are located where river conditions are ideal for generating and that,
while they are not generally located within one mile, there may be some
projects owned by affiliates that are within 10 miles of each
other.\757\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\757\ New England Small Hydro Comments at 17.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
485. Borrego Solar opposes applying the proposed changes to the
one-mile rule to distributed generation and finds that it would
restrict the ability of developers to follow market signals when
locating projects and significantly increase the regulatory burden.
Borrego Solar notes that there are several reasons that otherwise
different projects from the same company would be within 10 miles of
each other, including land zoning restrictions, available substation
capacity, and optimal topology or insolation.\758\ Borrego Solar notes
that it is common for projects on the distribution system to be within
two miles of a substation or three-phase lines to reduce
interconnection costs. Borrego Solar states that it is also common for
multiple unaffiliated developers to site their projects in a single
area within just a few miles of each other, and later sell those
projects to a single entity much later in the process, inadvertently
violating the Commission's rules.\759\ Borrego Solar would like the
Commission to exclude projects directly interconnected to the
distribution system or initially developed by different entities from
any presumption of common development. Borrego Solar urges the
Commission to, at a minimum, establish a streamlined, low-cost option
for challenging any presumption of common development, to avoid casting
a chill over project development and driving developers and long-term
owners out of the market due to the risks of having the projects
disqualified.\760\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\758\ Borrego Solar Comments at 3-4.
\759\ Id. at 4.
\760\ Id. at 5.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
486. North Carolina DOJ argues that the proposed rule, by
discouraging facilities from being placed close to one another, also
runs counter to a North Carolina policy based on efficient use of
electric resources.\761\ North Carolina DOJ and North Carolina
Commission Staff state that the rules in North Carolina incentivize the
installation of production facilities close to substations so projects
naturally appear in clusters surrounding transmission and distribution
infrastructure.\762\ North Carolina DOJ says that the proposed rule
fails to take into account the complex and regionally specific factors
driving the siting, financing, operation, and maintenance of production
facilities.\763\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\761\ North Carolina DOJ Comments at 8.
\762\ Id.; North Carolina Commission Staff Comments at 6.
\763\ North Carolina DOJ Comments at 6.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
487. Industrial Energy Consumers state that the NOPR does not
distinguish between merchant small power production QFs built to sell
electricity to third parties and self-supply QFs built primarily to
support manufacturing or industrial processes. Industrial Energy
Consumers state that there are many manufacturing company sites that
are of a 10-mile length. Industrial Energy Consumers state that the
Commission's proposed changes to the one-mile rule should be clarified
to exclude ``self-supply'' QFs.\764\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\764\ Industrial Energy Consumers Comments at 16.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
488. Solar Energy Industries believes that for facilities less than
one mile
[[Page 54699]]
apart the Commission should continue to waive the rule where
appropriate.\765\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\765\ Solar Energy Industries Comments at 60-61 (citing
Windfarms, Ltd., 13 FERC ] 61,017, at 61,032 (1980) (Windfarms)).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
489. Regarding the proposed irrebuttable presumption that
facilities located more than 10 miles apart are separate facilities,
NorthWestern urges the Commission to consider increasing the distance.
NorthWestern explains that its operations in Montana are geographically
very expansive and 10 miles in Montana is not a substantial distance,
especially when compared to other states that are geographically much
smaller. NorthWestern states that Montana's electric system has more
than 24,450 miles of electric transmission and distribution lines to
serve approximately 374,000 customers, and that its electric operations
are very rural and cover more than 97,500 square miles.\766\
NorthWestern therefore recommends that the Commission consider
expanding this distance to accommodate utilities in the West that have
very large service territories.\767\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\766\ NorthWestern Comments at 10.
\767\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
ii. Commission Determination
490. We adopt the NOPR proposal that an entity can seek to rebut
the presumption of separate sites only for an entity seeking small
power production QF status with an affiliated small power production QF
or QFs that are located more than one and less than 10 miles from it.
491. We recognize, as we have previously for the one-mile
rule,\768\ that it is debatable as to where exactly these thresholds
are most appropriately set. PURPA requires that no small power
production facility, together with other facilities located ``at the
same site,'' exceed 80 MWs, and Congress has tasked the Commission with
defining what constitutes facilities being at the same site for
purposes of PURPA. We find that providing set geographic distances will
limit unnecessary disputes over whether facilities are at the same
site, and therefore must choose reasonable distances at which small
power production facilities will be considered irrebuttably at the same
site or irrebuttably at separate sites. There are some affiliated small
power production facilities using the same energy resource that are so
close together that it is reasonable to treat them as irrebuttably at
the same site. The Commission finds that one mile or less is a
reasonable distance to treat such facilities as irrebuttably at the
same site. Likewise, there are some small power production facilities
that are affiliated and may use the same energy resource but that are
sufficiently far apart that it is reasonable to treat them as
irrebuttably at separate sites. The Commission finds that 10 miles or
more is a reasonable distance to treat such facilities as irrebuttably
at separate sites. For affiliated small power production facilities
using the same resource that are more than one mile but less than 10
miles apart, the Commission finds that the distinction between same
site or separate site is not as clear, and therefore finds that it is
reasonable to treat them as rebuttably at separate sites, and to allow
interested parties to provide evidence to attempt to rebut that
presumption. The Commission finds that establishing these reasonable
distances, and particularly establishing the ability to rebut the
presumption of separate sites for affiliated small power production
facilities more than one mile but less than 10 miles apart, better
allows the Commission to address the evolving shape and configuration
of resources, such as modular solar or wind power plants, that are
being developed as QFs, and provides for improved administration of
PURPA. The Commission therefore finds that the one-mile and 10-mile
limits are reasonable inflection points for differentiating between the
same site and separate sites.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\768\ See Windfarms, 13 FERC at 61,032.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
492. The Commission understands that there may be many reasons that
guide developers' decisions on where to site facilities, and for siting
them near to (or far from) each other. The Commission reiterates that
for affiliated small power production QFs that are more than one and
less than 10 miles apart, there is still a presumption that they are at
separate sites, though the Commission today makes that presumption a
rebuttable presumption.\769\ We also adopt today the proposal to allow
an entity seeking QF status to provide further information in its
certification (both self-certification and application for Commission
certification) or recertification (both self-recertification and
application for Commission recertification) to preemptively defend
against rebuttal by identifying factors that affirmatively show that
its facility is indeed at a separate site from affiliated small power
production QFs more than one but less than 10 miles from it.
Additionally, we note that we are retaining waiver provision in 18 CFR
292.204(a)(3), allowing the Commission to waive the method of
calculation of the size of the facility for good cause.\770\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\769\ For hydroelectric generating facilities, the regulations
currently provide that the same energy resources essentially means
``the same impoundment for power generation,'' see 18 CFR
292.204(a)(2)(i), and it is unlikely that hydroelectric generating
facilities located more than a mile apart would rely on the same
impoundment. Should that circumstance arise, though, the applicant
facility could seek waiver, arguing that the facilities should not
be considered to be at the same site. See 18 CFR 292.204(a)(3).
\770\ See 18 CFR 292.204(a)(3).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
493. Borrego Solar raises the concern that unaffiliated developers
may site their projects within a few miles of each other, and later
sell those projects to a single entity much later in the process,
inadvertently violating the Commission's rules. The Commission finds
that it is reasonable to expect the single purchasing entity in the
example to be on notice about the size and locations of its QF
acquisitions and the requirements of both PURPA and the Commission's
regulations, just as it would need to consider other regulatory
requirements associated with its acquisition. Moreover, ownership by a
single entity of multiple small power production QFs in close proximity
to each other that together exceed a power production capacity of 80
MW, and whether this improperly circumvents the Commission's
regulations, is precisely what the new rebuttable presumption is
seeking to address.
494. Regarding Industrial Energy Consumers' request that the
Commission's changes be clarified to exclude ``self-supply'' QFs, the
Commission declines to do so. PURPA limits the power production
capacity of a small power production QF, together with any other
facilities located at the same site (as determined by the Commission),
to 80 MW.\771\ The Commission finds that Industrial Energy Consumer's
argument that ``self-supply'' QFs are built primarily to support
manufacturing and industrial processes does not negate the fact that
the ``self-supply'' QFs in question are small power production
facilities limited to 80 MW. Similarly, its argument also does not
justify different application of the same site determination. The
Commission will therefore apply the same site determinations to all
small power production QFs. The Commission notes that, as with other
small power production QFs, an individual ``self-supply'' QF may assert
relevant factors to show why it should not be considered to be at the
same site as an affiliated small power production QF that is more than
one but less than 10 miles away from it. For example, if a self-supply
facility seeking QF status was within 10 miles of an affiliated
[[Page 54700]]
small power production QF, but the energy from each facility was used
primarily to supply different end users, the self-supply facility
seeking QF status could argue that this fact supports that it is at a
separate site from the affiliated small power production QF, and the
Commission would consider this fact in its evaluation.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\771\ 16 U.S.C. 796(17)(A)(ii).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
495. Regarding Terna Energy's contention that the new rule causes a
100-times increase to the ``exclusion zone'' around a QF's electrical
generating equipment, we believe that the rule providing for a
rebuttable presumption for affiliated small power production QFs
located more than one but less than 10 miles apart, as promulgated
today, is necessary to address allegations of improper circumvention of
the one-mile rule that both previously and in comments have been
presented to the Commission.
496. We reject NorthWestern's request to increase the distance of
the irrebuttable presumption of separate sites to more than 10 miles.
Northwestern argues that 10 miles is not a significant distance
compared to the geographic expansiveness of its system. We believe this
is an irrelevant comparison; what matters is not how large or small the
purchasing electric utility's service territory is or how rural it may
be or how many miles of transmission lines it may have, but the
question presented by the statute, i.e., whether or not the affiliated
small power production QFs are located at the same site. As described
above, we have decided that 10 miles is a reasonable and appropriate
distance at which to apply the irrebuttable presumption of separate
sites, irrespective of how expansive, or diminutive, the purchasing
electric utility's system may be.
f. Factors
i. Comments
497. Several commenters state that they support the factors for
evaluating whether or not facilities are at the same site, which are
described in the NOPR.\772\ SC Solar Alliance and the Southeast Public
Interest Organizations support considering a common point of
interconnection or a single real estate parcel or owner as factors
weighing towards a determination that multiple projects are a single
facility.\773\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\772\ APPA Comments at 21-22; Connecticut Authority Comments at
19-20; Idaho Commission Comments at 6-7; NARUC Comments at 5;
Portland General Comments at 15.
\773\ SC Solar Alliance Comments at 17; Southeast Public
Interest Organization Comments at 34.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
498. Several commenters offer additional factors for
consideration.\774\ North Carolina Commission Staff states that the
Commission should also consider whether the QF is attempting to game
the system by getting rates for which they would otherwise be
ineligible, as well as where the facilities were constructed and when
common ownership commenced.\775\ Northern Laramie Range Alliance
suggests that relevant factors could include, for example, direct or
indirect ownership by the same party or parties, interconnection at a
single substation, simultaneous site acquisition and/or state and local
permitting.\776\ Allco proposes that the criteria to determine if sites
are separate should be whether they share infrastructure, private roads
or interconnection agreements in common.\777\ NRECA proposes that the
types of evidence could include evidence of contemporaneous
construction, shared interconnection, common communication and control,
use of the same step-up transformer, and common permitting and land
leasing.\778\ The Idaho Commission proposes that relevant factors
include whether they share an interconnection agreement, obtained
local, state or federal permits under the same application or as the
same entity, and if they have a revenue sharing agreement.\779\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\774\ Allco Comments at 16; Idaho Commission Comments at 6-7;
North Carolina Commission Staff Comments at 6; Northern Laramie
Range Alliance Comments at 3; NRECA Comments at 15-16.
\775\ North Carolina Commission Staff Comments at 6.
\776\ Northern Laramie Range Alliance Comments at 3.
\777\ Allco Comments at 16.
\778\ NRECA Comments at 15-16.
\779\ Idaho Commission Comments at 6-7.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Portland General suggests that the Commission include past
ownership of projects as a factor.\780\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\780\ Portland General Comments at 15.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
499. Regarding the relative weight of the factors, the Southeast
Public Interest Organizations would like the Commission to identify
which factors would be definitive in a QF being able to proactively
demonstrate that their site is separate.\781\ Both Basin and EEI would
like the Commission to clarify that the list of factors to be
considered is not exhaustive or weighted.\782\ NorthWestern contends
that the Commission should specify that a showing of any one factor is
sufficient to rebut the presumption. NorthWestern argues that the
Commission should have the flexibility to deal with this issue on a
case-by-case basis and expand or modify the list of factors where
appropriate.\783\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\781\ Southeast Public Interest Organization Comments at 34.
\782\ Basin Comments at 12; EEI Comments at 45.
\783\ NorthWestern Comments at 11.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
500. NorthWestern states that it has concerns about the
Commission's reliance on 18 CFR 35.36(a)(9), because, according to
NorthWestern, developers carefully structure the ownership of their
companies to ensure that they are not, technically, legal affiliates
when, in fact, considering the totality of the circumstances, they are
affiliates. For these reasons, NorthWestern strongly urges the
Commission to consider the physical characteristic factors identified
for determining the distance between facilities in order to also
determine if facilities are owned by affiliates.\784\ NorthWestern
states that, for example, if one facility only owns five percent voting
interest in another facility, but the two facilities have one
interconnection request and use the same collector system, the
Commission should be able to find that there are sufficient facts so
that they are treated as affiliates for purposes of the one-mile
rule.\785\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\784\ Id. at 12.
\785\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
501. Several commenters opposed the Commission's proposed
factors.\786\ SC Solar Alliance states that the range of factors
included under the categories of ``ownership/other characteristics''
and ``physical characteristics'' is overly broad and could be subject
to inconsistent or problematic interpretation. For example, SC Solar
Alliance states that the term ``infrastructure'' is undefined and
ambiguous, and ``control facilities,'' ``access and easements,''
``collector systems or facilities,'' and ``property leases'' are all
vague and imprecise.\787\ SC Solar Alliance agrees with Solar Energy
Industries' emphasis that under no scenario should common financing be
relevant, as unquestionably distinct facilities are frequently financed
as part of a bundled portfolio.\788\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\786\ Ares Comments at 5-7; Borrego Solar Comments at 3-4;
NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 73; Solar Energy Industries
Comments at 62; SC Solar Alliance Comments at 16-18; Southeast
Public Interest Organizations Comments at 34.
\787\ SC Solar Alliance Comments at 17.
\788\ Id. at 16 (citing Solar Energy Industries Supplemental
Comments, Docket No. AD16-16, at 55-56 (August 28, 2019)).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
502. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA strongly oppose use of common
interconnection facilities as a factor because separately owned
facilities are likely to share interconnection facilities to reduce
costs and build off of existing infrastructure. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and
OSEIA state that, given that there are only a limited number of
qualified
[[Page 54701]]
maintenance providers and other service contractors, the fact that two
facilities use the same contractors should not be relevant to common
ownership and control of two facilities. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA
state that the fact that two facilities are constructed within 12
months of each other could merely be evidence that the market
conditions at the time favored construction of the facilities, not that
the facilities are intended to be one facility.\789\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\789\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 73-74.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
503. SC Solar Alliance states that the extensive list of
``ownership/other characteristics'' as written is highly problematic.
Control and maintenance, particularly in North and South Carolina where
there are a substantial number of distributed solar facilities, is
often contracted for by a limited number of solar maintenance
companies. Allowing the existence of a common maintenance company to in
any way dictate QF status is entirely unreasonable and bears no
relationship to the question at hand.\790\ Similarly, other factors
included in the NOPR, including the sale of electricity to a common
utility, a common financing lender, the use of a mutual contractor for
project construction, the timing of contract execution, and the timing
of facilities being placed into service do not provide relevant
evidence as to common ownership requiring facilities to be considered a
single QF. Applying these factors would create an unnecessary and undue
burden on QFs, particularly smaller distribution-connected QFs that
have been constructed relatively nearby and which often rely on a
limited number of local contractors and partners to complete this
necessary work.\791\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\790\ SC Solar Alliance Comments at 17-18.
\791\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
504. The Southeast Public Interest Organizations are concerned that
the use of common contractors, financing entity, maintenance companies,
or sales to the same entity and such could be used against QFs that are
built in the same area but are otherwise separate sites.\792\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\792\ Southeast Public Interest Organizations Comments at 34.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
505. SC Solar Alliance states that the Commission's statement that
``no single factor would be dispositive'' is troubling, and that it is
inconceivable that QF ownership would not be dispositive in any such
rebuttable presumption. SC Solar Alliance states that it would be
wholly unjust and unreasonable to consider a solar facility owned by
one solar developer to be considered part of a solar facility owned by
a distinct and unaffiliated solar developer. SC Solar Alliance states
that any rebuttable presumption should include ``separate ownership''
as a dispositive indication of separate facilities.\793\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\793\ SC Solar Alliance Comments at 17.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
506. North Carolina DOJ states that the element of common control
is a challenging question because of the limited number of companies
available to operate renewable energy facilities. North Carolina DOJ
asserts that a handful of firms are responsible for the operation and
maintenance work for close to half of the country's solar energy
production facilities.\794\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\794\ North Carolina DOJ Comments at 8.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
507. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA state that the Commission should
include substantially more specific parameters about what evidence a
project would need to submit to demonstrate single-project status and
should make clear that this test has no applicability unless generators
within one to 10 miles are owned by the same company or affiliates of
the same company. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA assert that ``the
decisive factors are the `stream of benefits' from the project and
control of the venture,'' which the Commission defined ``to include
entitlement to profits, losses, and surplus after return of initial
capital contribution.'' \795\ These criteria could be used to
objectively evaluate whether two QFs within 10 miles are commonly owned
or controlled, as opposed to also putting two separately owned and
controlled facilities at risk of violating the rule based solely on
physical characteristics.\796\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\795\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 73 (citing CMS
Midland, Inc., 50 FERC ] 61,098, at 61,278-279 (1990), aff'd Mich.
Municipal Coop. Group v. FERC, 990 F.2d 1377 (D.C. Cir. 1993)).
\796\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
ii. Commission Determination
508. We adopt the physical and ownership factors proposed in the
NOPR, including as noted above the ability of a QF to preemptively
identify the factors in its filing in anticipation of protests to its
filing. As explained above in section IV.D.1.d we are modifying the
NOPR proposal to change terminology relating to the determination of
whether facilities are separate facilities to focus not on whether they
are separate facilities, but rather to mirror the statutory language
and thus focus on whether they are at ``the same site.'' Accordingly,
we adopt these factors as relevant indicia of whether affiliated small
power production facilities are ``at the same site.'' In addition, we
modify the NOPR proposal to identify the following additional physical
factors as indicia that small power production facilities should be
considered to be located at the same site: (1) Evidence of shared
control systems; (2) common permitting and land leasing; and (3) shared
step-up transformers.
509. Specifically, we adopt the factors listed below as examples of
the factors the Commission may consider in deciding whether small power
production facilities that are owned by the same person(s) or its
affiliates are located ``at the same site'': (1) Physical
characteristics, including such common characteristics as:
Infrastructure, property ownership, property leases, control
facilities, access and easements, interconnection agreements,
interconnection facilities up to the point of interconnection to the
distribution or transmission system, collector systems or facilities,
points of interconnection, motive force or fuel source, off-take
arrangements, connections to the electrical grid, evidence of shared
control systems, common permitting and land leasing, and shared step-up
transformers; and (2) ownership/other characteristics, including such
characteristics as whether the facilities in question are: Owned or
controlled by the same person(s) or affiliated persons(s),\797\
operated and maintained by the same or affiliated entity(ies), selling
to the same electric utility, using common debt or equity financing,
constructed by the same entity within 12 months, managing a power sales
agreement executed within 12 months of a similar and affiliated small
power production qualifying facility in the same location, placed into
service within 12 months of an affiliated small power production QF
project's commercial operation date as specified in the power sales
agreement, or sharing engineering or procurement contracts.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\797\ Definitionally, if the facilities are not owned by the
same person(s) or its affiliates, then the issue of compliance with
the one-mile rule, even as revised in this final rule, becomes
irrelevant. See 18 CFR 292.204(a)(1). That is, two facilities owned
by two different persons are definitionally not located at the same
site.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
510. We adopt the NOPR proposal to allow a small power production
facility seeking QF status to provide further information in its
certification (both self-certification and application for Commission
certification) or recertification (both self-recertification and
application for Commission recertification) to preemptively defend
against rebuttal, by identifying factors that affirmatively show that
its facility is indeed at a separate site from
[[Page 54702]]
affiliated small power production QFs more than one but less than 10
miles away from it. Any party challenging the QF certification (both
self-certification and application for Commission certification) or
recertification (both self-recertification and application for
Commission recertification) that makes substantive changes to the
existing certification would, in its protest, be allowed to
correspondingly identify factors to show that the small power
production facility seeking QF status and affiliated small power
production QFs more than one but less than 10 from that facility are
actually at the same site.
511. We reiterate that, as a general matter, no one factor is
dispositive.\798\ Rather, we will conduct a case-by-case analysis,
weighing the evidence for and against, and the more compelling the
showing that affiliated small power production QFs should be considered
to be at the same site as the small power production facility seeking
QF status in a specific case, the more likely the Commission will be to
find that the facilities involved in that case are indeed located ``at
the same site.''
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\798\ But see supra note 797.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
g. Exemptions
i. Comments
512. Ares notes that small power producers have certain exemptions
from utility regulation, including exemptions from FPA sections 203 and
204 if under 30 MW and exemptions from FPA sections 205 and 206 if
under 20 MW (or 30 MW in special cases), as well as exemptions from
some state utility laws and PUHCA if under 30 MW.\799\ Ares is
concerned that the rebuttable presumption and the factors will make
many small power QFs ineligible for these exemptions.\800\ Ares argues
that the aggregation of small power QFs may result in many required
applications for market-based rate authority for sales that are minor.
Ares argues that the Commission has no basis for, did not consider, and
has sought no comments on the removal of regulatory obligations when
small power QFs are aggregated under the new ten-mile proposal.\801\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\799\ Ares Comments at 4-5.
\800\ Id. at 5-6.
\801\ Id. at 11-12.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
513. Solar Energy Industries note that many facilities could lose
their FPA and PUHCA exemptions if there are multiple facilities within
10 miles, which is particularly harmful to QFs that are not selling to
their host utility. Solar Energy Industries state that PURPA section
210(e)(1) instructs that the Commission shall exempt QFs from
regulation if such exemption ``is necessary to encourage cogeneration
and small power production.'' \802\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\802\ Solar Energy Industries Comments at 55.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
ii. Commission Determination
514. The Commission's current one-mile rule is a rule used to
measure, ultimately, whether or not small power production facilities
are within PURPA's limit on small power production QFs of 80 MW, and
thus whether such facilities are QFs, and the Commission has
consistently applied the one-mile rule generally to the regulations
issued pursuant to PURPA.\803\ There is no persuasive reason it should
not be equally applied in the context of the regulations implementing
section 210(e) of PURPA. That being said, we are not removing or
amending the exemptions provided by the regulations implementing PURPA
section 210(e). If a QF qualifies for exemptions pursuant to PURPA
section 210(e) and the Commission's implementing regulations,\804\ then
that QF is entitled to those exemptions. But, if a small power
production facility does not meet the 80 MW limit for whatever reason,
including because an affiliated small power production QF is located at
the same site, then it does not qualify for such exemption because it
would not be a QF.\805\ There is nothing inappropriate about this
consequence; a facility that is not a QF is not entitled to the
exemptions available to QFs. We further note that there will now be a
rebuttable presumption that affiliated small power production QFs
located more than one but less than 10 miles apart are indeed located
at separate sites. That is no different than the one-mile rule as it
has long existed. What is different is that, with this final rule, the
presumption will be rebuttable while before it was irrebuttable; the
presumption that the facilities are at separate sites, though, remains
unchanged. Only if a party rebuts that presumption and shows that the
small power production facility seeking QF status and affiliated small
power production QFs should be viewed as located at the same site will
the capacity of such facilities be counted together. In that event, if
the small power production facility seeking QF status and affiliated
small power production QFs located at the same site have a combined
power production capacity that exceeds 80 MW, the entity seeking QF
status would not qualify as a QF and would properly not be entitled to
the exemptions that are available to QFs.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\803\ SunE B9 Holdings LLC, 157 FERC ] 61,044, at P 16 & n.24
(2016) (citing Windfarms, 13 FERC ] 61,017 at 61,031).
\804\ 18 CFR 292.601, 292.602.
\805\ See 16 U.S.C. 796(17)(A)(ii).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
2. Electrical Generating Equipment
a. NOPR Proposal
515. The Commission proposed defining ``electrical generating
equipment'' to refer to all boilers, heat recovery steam generators,
prime movers (any mechanical equipment driving an electric generator),
electrical generators, photovoltaic solar panels and/or inverters, fuel
cell equipment and/or other primary power generation equipment used in
the facility, excluding equipment for gathering energy to be used in
the facility. The Commission expected that each wind turbine on a wind
farm and each solar panel in a solar facility would be considered
``electrical generating equipment'' because each wind turbine and each
solar panel is independently capable of producing electric energy. The
Commission sought comments on this approach, and on what equipment--if
not individual wind turbines and solar panels--should be considered
``electrical generating equipment'' for wind and solar plants.
516. The Commission also proposed specifying how to measure the
distance between facilities that have multiple, separate sets of
``electrical generating equipment'' such as wind farms and solar
facilities. The Commission proposed measuring the distance between the
nearest ``electrical generating equipment'' of any two facilities such
that, for the facilities to be presumed irrebuttably separate, all such
equipment of one QF must be at least 10 miles away from all such
equipment of another QF. The Commission believed this is the
appropriate way to measure the distance between affiliated sets of
``electrical generating equipment'' because this reflects the distance
between the components directly tied to producing electric energy.
517. The Commission sought comment on this approach, and whether
alternative approaches would be more appropriate. For example, some
parties had suggested in QF certification proceedings that the
Commission could use the geographic center of the plant footprint or a
weighted average of the locations of the individual pieces of
``electrical generating equipment.'' \806\ The Commission was concerned
these approaches could be easily gamed, but sought comment on whether
they may be constructed in a way that would prevent gaming, and whether
such
[[Page 54703]]
formulations would be preferable to the proposed approach.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\806\ See Beaver Creek Wind II, LLC, 160 FERC ] 61,052, at P 9
(2017).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
b. Comments
518. Many commenters support the definition of ``electrical
generating equipment'' proposed in the NOPR.\807\ However, ELCON
objects to both the proposed definition of ``electric generating
equipment'' and the approach to measuring distance.\808\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\807\ Alliant Energy Comments at 19; APPA Comments at 23; Basin
Comments at 11; Connecticut Authority Comments at 19-20; EEI
Comments at 49; Idaho Commission Comments at 6; Kentucky Commission
Comments at 7; NRECA Comments at 17; Portland General Comments at
16-17; Southeast Public Interest Organizations Comments at 37-38.
\808\ ELCON Comments at 36.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
519. Many commenters support the method for measuring distance
between sites proposed in the NOPR, which would require measuring the
distance between the nearest ``electrical generating equipment'' of any
two affiliated facilities.\809\ Several commenters note their
opposition to measuring the distance between sites using the geographic
center of the plant or a weighted average of the locations of
individual pieces of ``electrical generating equipment,'' both methods
the Commission sought comment on in the NOPR.\810\ The Southeast Public
Interest Organizations request clarification of whether to measure from
the edge of a solar panel or the center of a solar array.\811\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\809\ Alliant Energy Comments at 19; APPA Comments at 23; Basin
Comments at 11; Connecticut Authority Comments at 19-20; EEI
Comments at 49; Kentucky Commission Comments at 7; NARUC Comments at
4-5; Portland General Comments at 16-17; Southeast Public Interest
Organizations Comments at 37-38.
\810\ Connecticut Authority Comments at 21; Kentucky Commission
Comments at 7; NorthWestern Comments at 12-13; NRECA Comments at 18;
Portland General Comments at 18.
\811\ Southeast Public Interest Organizations Comments at 38.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
520. Several commenters request that the Commission discuss how
energy storage (sometimes referred to as battery storage) would be
considered in relation to the proposed definition of electrical
generating equipment.\812\ The California Commission requests that a
battery storage facility be excluded from consideration as electrical
generating equipment provided the storage is charged solely by the
small power production facility, and that energy stored by the storage
facility be considered to be of the same energy source of that energy
before it was stored.\813\ The California Commission also requests that
the Commission affirm that storage does not permit a facility to exceed
the maximum size criteria of a small power production facility.\814\
EEI requests that the Form 556 collect data on storage resources as
well as electrical generating equipment for purposes of measuring
distance to an affiliated small power production QF.\815\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\812\ Alliant Energy Comments at 19; EEI Comments at 46-47;
Energy Storage Comments at 3; NorthWestern Comments at 13.
\813\ California Commission at 16-17.
\814\ Id. at 15.
\815\ EEI at 51-52.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
c. Commission Determination
521. We adopt the NOPR proposal that ``electrical generating
equipment'' refers to all boilers, heat recovery steam generators,
prime movers (any mechanical equipment driving an electric generator),
electrical generators, photovoltaic solar panels, inverters, fuel cell
equipment and/or other primary power generation equipment used in the
facility, excluding equipment for gathering energy to be used in the
facility. Each wind turbine at a wind facility and each solar panel in
a solar facility would be considered ``electrical generating
equipment'' because each wind turbine and each solar panel is
independently capable of producing electric energy.
522. We require the distance between the facility seeking small
power production QF status and any affiliated small power production
QFs using the same energy resource to be measured by the distance
between the nearest ``electrical generating equipment'' of each such
facility, such that, for the entity seeking QF status to be presumed
irrebuttably at a separate site from any affiliated small power
production QF, all such equipment of the affiliated small power
production QF must be at least 10 miles away from all such equipment of
the entity seeking small power production QF status. The Commission
finds that this is the most appropriate way to measure the distance
between affiliated sets of ``electrical generating equipment'' at small
power production facilities because this reflects the distance between
the components directly tied to producing electric energy.
523. The point used in the distance calculation will always be from
the edge of the electrical generating equipment closest to the
affiliated small power production QF's nearest electrical generating
equipment. Thus, we clarify that for a solar facility, the measurement
should be from the edge of the small power production facility seeking
QF status' solar panel or inverter that is closest to the edge of the
nearest ``electrical generating equipment'' of that affiliated small
power production QF. For a wind facility, the measurement should
similarly be from the edge of the small power production facility
seeking QF status' wind turbine or inverter closest to the edge of the
nearest ``electrical generating equipment'' of the affiliated small
power production QF. For a wind facility, we clarify that the relevant
point for measuring distance of an individual wind turbine is the tower
(not the projection of the blade's wingspans onto the ground). We also
clarify that only horizontal distances are taken into consideration for
purposes of this rule (such that elevation changes have no effect on
facility distance).
524. We find that the role of battery storage in QFs, including
with regard to the distance between QFs, is beyond the scope in this
proceeding.
E. QF Certification Process
1. NOPR Proposal
525. In the NOPR, the Commission proposed to revise 18 CFR
292.207(a) to allow interested persons to intervene in, and to file a
protest of a self-certification or self-recertification of a facility
without the necessity of filing a separate petition for declaratory
order and without having to pay the filing fee required for a
declaratory order. Because an applicant for self-certification or self-
recertification is required to serve a copy of its submission on
interested electric utilities (principally those with which it is
interconnected and those to which it will be selling) as well as the
relevant state regulatory authorities, the Commission proposed to allow
interested persons 30 days from the date of filing at the Commission to
intervene and/or to file a protest (without paying a filing fee).\816\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\816\ 18 CFR 292.207(c)(1).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
526. Any party submitting a protest would have the burden of
specifying facts that make a prima facie demonstration that the
facility described in the self-certification or self-recertification
does not satisfy the requirements for QF status. General allegations
that the facility is not a QF without reference to the specific
regulatory provision that has not been satisfied (and without an
explanation why the provision has not been satisfied), or unsupported
assertions that the self-certification does not satisfy an aspect of
the PURPA Regulations, would not satisfy this burden and would not be a
basis for denial of certification. However, if this prima facie burden
is met, then the burden would shift to the applicant submitting the
self-certification or self-
[[Page 54704]]
recertification to demonstrate that the claims raised in the protest
are incorrect and that certification is, in fact, warranted.
527. QF self-certification is effective upon filing and would
remain effective if a protest is filed, until such time as the
Commission rules that certification is revoked. The Commission proposed
that it would issue an order within 90 days of the date the protest is
filed. The Commission also reserved the right to request more
information from the protester, the entity seeking QF status, or
both.\817\ If the Commission requests more information, the time period
for the Commission order would be extended to 60 days from the filing
of a complete answer to the information request.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\817\ Such information requests could be issued by the
Commission or by staff under any applicable delegated authority. For
example, under 18 CFR 375.307(b)(3)(ii), the Director of the Office
of Energy Market Regulation is authorized to ``[i]ssue and sign
requests for additional information regarding applications, filings,
reports and data processed by the Office of Energy Market
Regulation.''
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
528. There may be instances, however, when the Commission may need
additional time to review the record in light of the nature of the
protests. In those cases, the Commission proposed that, in addition to
any extension resulting from a request for information, the Commission
also may toll the 90-day period during which the Commission commits to
act within one additional 60-day period. The Commission proposed to
delegate to the Commission's Secretary, or the Secretary's designee,
the authority to toll the 90-day period for this purpose.
529. The Commission believed these procedures would allow for
timely but thorough review of protested self-certifications and self-
recertifications. The Commission sought comment on whether these
procedures impose an undue burden on the QF even though the QF remains
certified pending the review.
2. Comments
530. Many commenters raise the issue of granting legacy treatment,
colloquially known as ``grandfathering,'' to existing QF certifications
and their future recertifications.\818\ Most of these comments support
granting legacy treatment to current QFs and their future
recertifications.\819\ Several commenters note that the application of
the rule to existing or recertifying QFs will create uncertainty and
cause disruptions of the sale of these QFs.\820\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\818\ Ares Comments at 12; Basin Comments at 11; BluEarth
Comments at 2; DC Commission at 9; New England Small Hydro Comments
at 17; Industrial Energy Consumers Comments at 17; NIPPC, CREA, REC,
and OSEIA Comments at 74; Solar Energy Industries Comments at 61-63;
SC Solar Alliance Comments at 18; Southeast Public Interest
Organizations Comments at 29-31; Terna Energy Comments at 16-18.
\819\ Ares Comments at 12; BluEarth Comments at 2; New England
Small Hydro Comments at 17; Industrial Energy Consumers Comments at
17; NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 74; Solar Energy
Industries Comments at 61-63; SC Solar Alliance Comments at 18;
Southeast Public Interest Organizations Comments at 29-31; Terna
Energy Comments at 16-18.
\820\ New England Small Hydro Comments at 17; NIPPC, CREA, REC,
and OSEIA Comments at 74; Terna Energy Comments at 16-18.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
531. New England Small Hydro warns that applying the proposed rule
to existing QFs could trigger financing defaults if those QFs lose
their status.\821\ The Southeast Public Interest Organizations state
that the proposed rebuttable presumption has implications for existing
solar QFs in the Southeast, noting that QFs would be required to seek
recertification as their existing PPAs expire, adding a significant
burden.\822\ The Southeast Public Interest Organizations provide maps
showing the ten-mile radius of utility-scale projects could lead to
many overlapping affiliated territories under the new rules.\823\ SC
Solar Alliance also notes the large number of small solar QFs
overlapping within a ten-mile radius across North Carolina and South
Carolina and finds that the application of the more-than-one-but-less-
than-10-miles rebuttable presumption to recertifications will be
burdensome and unwieldy.\824\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA warn that the
application of the new rule to existing QFs will effectively bar the
transfer or sale (or potentially any number of less significant
changes) of existing assets that were lawfully qualified under the one-
mile rule but would pass the 80 MW aggregate threshold under the new
rule. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA find this to be a violation of the
existing QFs contractual and constitutional rights.\825\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\821\ New England Small Hydro Comments at 17.
\822\ Southeast Public Interest Organizations Comments at 29.
\823\ Id. at 30-31.
\824\ SC Solar Alliance Comments at 18.
\825\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 75.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
532. Terna Energy states that granting legacy treatment to existing
QFs and their recertifications is necessary to protect investment
decisions and contracts made under the long-standing one-mile
rule.\826\ Terna Energy contends that, without clarification on the
legacy treatment of recertifications, QFs could lose their status even
for non-substantive revisions to their FERC Form No. 556s such as
contact information, street address, ownership or operation.\827\ Terna
Energy warns that absent the clarification of legacy treatment for
existing QF recertifications, QFs might go to extremes to avoid
updating their FERC Form No. 556s with information changes.\828\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\826\ Terna Energy Comments at 1-2.
\827\ Id. at 2.
\828\ Id. at 7.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
533. Solar Energy Industries state that retroactively applying a
more-than-one-but-less-than-10-miles rebuttable presumption to physical
facilities that were developed based on the original one-mile rule will
inject instability, will erode trust from the investment community, and
will discourage the development of QFs as well as investment in the
industry in general.\829\ Ares notes that not granting legacy treatment
to existing QFs is inconsistent with past Commission actions on PURPA,
such as the granting of legacy treatment to existing QF contracts in
Order No. 671 or other QF related proceedings.\830\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\829\ Solar Energy Industries Comments at 62.
\830\ Ares Comments at 12.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
534. New England Small Hydro supports granting legacy treatment to
existing QFs to avoid upsetting the settled expectations of existing
generation.\831\ New England Small Hydro gives the example of three
hypothetical projects, each located nine miles apart that, when
capacities are totaled, exceed 80 MW. If there is an ownership change
that triggers the need for a recertification but the entities remain
affiliates, under the Commission's proposed rule, all three projects
would lose QF status. According to New England Small Hydro, this could
trigger defaults under financing documents and the utility might be
able to terminate the power contract, because many PPAs for QFs require
the project to remain a QF for the term of the PPA. New England Small
Hydro states that, as a result, a minor ownership change could have
cascading negative effects to QFs.\832\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\831\ New England Small Hydro Comments at 17.
\832\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
535. Terna Energy requests that existing QFs be granted legacy
treatment as long as they do not make changes to electrical generating
equipment of the facility, because that is the equipment that
determines compliance with the one-mile rule. Terna Energy argues that
otherwise an existing QF could be subject to challenge anytime it makes
a non-substantive revision to its FERC Form No. 556, including a change
to contact information, street address, ownership, or operator,
effectively
[[Page 54705]]
eliminating legacy treatment.\833\ Terna Energy states that granting
legacy treatment is necessary to protect the sanctity of investments
and contracts made in reliance upon the Commission's current PURPA
regulations and the one-mile rule.\834\ Terna Energy submits revised
language for 18 CFR 292.204(a)(2) and (3) to clarify that existing QF
recertifications, unless they change the electrical generating
equipment, should not be subject to the new rules.\835\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\833\ Terna Energy Comments at 2.
\834\ Id. at 1-2.
\835\ Id. at 8-9.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
536. Basin, on the other hand, asks the Commission to be clear that
recertifications filed by QFs will trigger application of the proposed
rule.\836\ Basin also recommends the Commission allow petitions seeking
de-certification of QFs that have previously filed self-certifications
because some QFs self-certify at an early stage of project development
and ultimately never proceed to development.\837\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\836\ Basin Comments at 11.
\837\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
537. The DC Commission would like the Commission to clarify whether
the changes to the one-mile rule will apply to QFs under construction
when the rule goes into effect.\838\ The DC Commission would like the
Commission to leave the issue of legacy treatment of existing QFs up to
the states.\839\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\838\ DC Commission Comments at 9.
\839\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
538. Several commenters oppose the NOPR proposal to allow a party
to protest a self-certification or self-recertification of a facility
without being required to file a separate petition for declaratory
order and pay the associated filing fee.\840\ Several commenters argue
that this proposal will lead to a flood of challenges that will
discourage the growth of QFs.\841\ Several commenters state that there
will be substantial costs associated with this proposal that will fall
on ratepayers and QFs.\842\ Several commenters state that the proposed
changes will lead to increased administrative burden and expense \843\
or litigation risk.\844\ Several commenters state that the proposed
changes will lead to uncertainty \845\ and deter development.\846\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\840\ Allco Comments at 21; BluEarth Comments at 3; CARE
Comments at 7; Con Edison Comments at 5; Distributed Sun Comments at
3; ENGIE Comments at 4; Public Interest Organizations Comments at 9,
97-98; Western Resource Councils Comments at 144; Solar Energy
Industries Comments at 57-59.
\841\ Allco Comments at 21; BluEarth Comments at 3; Distributed
Sun Comments at 3; Public Interest Organizations Comments at 97;
Western Resource Councils Comments at 144.
\842\ Con Edison Comments at 5; ENGIE Comments at 4; Public
Interest Organizations Comments at 97; Solar Energy Industries
Comments at 58.
\843\ Ares Comments at 6; Borrego Solar Comments at 4; Con
Edison Comments at 5; Public Interest Organizations Comments at 97-
98; Solar Energy Industries Comments at 51-52, 54, 57-58; SC Solar
Alliance Comments at 15-18; Southeast Public Interest Organizations
Comments at 29, 35; sPower Comments at 14.
\844\ Con Edison Comments at 5; Distributed Sun Comments at 3;
ELCON Comments at 19-20; NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 71-
72; Public Interest Organizations Comments at 97-98; Solar Energy
Industries Comments at 58-60; SC Solar Alliance Comments at 16, 18;
Southeast Public Interest Organizations Comments at 29,35; sPower
Comments at 14.
\845\ Ares Comments at 9; Distributed Sun Comments at 3; ELCON
Comments at 19-20, 38; NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 69-
72; Public Interest Organizations Comments at 97-98; Solar Energy
Industries Comments at 58-60, 62-63; SC Solar Alliance Comments at
16, 18; Southeast Public Interest Organizations Comments at 29, 35,
38, 93, 97-98; sPower Comments at 14.
\846\ Allco Comments at 16; Borrego Solar Comments at 4-5;
Biological Diversity Comments at 9; Con Edison Comments at 4-5;
Distributed Sun Comments at 3; NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments
at 72-73; North Carolina DOJ Comments at 8; Public Interest
Organizations Comments at 93, 99; Solar Energy Industries Comments
at 51-52, 59-63; SC Solar Alliance Comments at 2, 18; Southeast
Public Interest Organizations Comments at 31-36, 38, 93.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
539. Solar Energy Industries state that the proposed changes to the
one-mile rule will substantially increase the regulatory burden on QFs
and the self-certification process will no longer be quick.\847\ Solar
Energy Industries is concerned that QFs may need to defend numerous
self-certifications over a facility's lifetime, and assert that QFs
could be forced to recertify any time the information represented in
the Form No. 556 changes, including ownership changes to affiliated
facilities located within 10 miles.\848\ Solar Energy Industries state
that the burden will be increased exponentially if the one-mile rule is
expanded in a ten-mile rule.\849\ Solar Energy Industries state that
the NOPR's estimate of an additional eight hours and $632 per docket
for each QF self-certification or re-certification is a substantial
underestimation.\850\ Solar Energy Industries estimate that it would
require an additional approximately 90 to 120 hours per year to comply
with the new requirements. Solar Energy Industries state that a QF
could be forced to recertify any time the information represented
changes, including ownership changes to affiliated facilities located
within 10 miles. Solar Energy Industries note that a QF may have to
engage in multiple defenses of its status, each time needing to engage
legal counsel and devote internal company resources to preserve the
status of its already-installed plant.\851\ Solar Energy Industries
assert that the flood of self-certification filings and updates would
be a substantial burden on Commission staff and provide little value to
the Commission or the public.\852\ Solar Energy Industries also state
that, unless and until the Commission makes a determination on the
burden associated with collecting, reporting, and updating the
Connected Entity \853\ information, it would be unjust and unreasonable
for the Commission to impose similar burdens on QF entities through the
FERC Form No. 556.\854\ Solar Energy Industries state that the
increased regulatory burden that will arise for these entities is
similar in scope and the Commission has not provided a rationale for
the increased information collection requirements.\855\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\847\ Solar Energy Industries Comments at 52.
\848\ Solar Energy Industries at 57.
\849\ Id. at 53.
\850\ Id. at 52.
\851\ Id. at 58.
\852\ Id. at 53-54.
\853\ Id. at 54 (citing Data Collection for Analytics and
Surveillance and Market-Based Rate Purposes, Order No. 860, 168 FERC
] 61,039, at P 183 (2019)).
\854\ Id. at 54, 57.
\855\ Id. at 54.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
540. Allco describes the Commission's Regulatory Flexibility Act
(RFA) analysis of the proposed rules' effect on small businesses as
improperly limited to proposed paperwork changes, ignoring the impact
on small QFs' abilities to construct facilities.\856\ Allco states that
the Commission did not attempt to minimize the impacts on small
renewable energy producers, consider alternative structures, or
describe these steps or considerations in a mandatory final RFA
analysis.\857\ Allco asserts that the Commission failed to support its
finding that the NOPR's proposed revisions will not significantly
impact a substantial number of small entities (specifically, solar
energy QFs); Allco therefore claims that the Commission violated the
Small Business Regulatory Enforcement Fairness Act.\858\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\856\ Allco Comments at 33.
\857\ Id.
\858\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
541. Solar Energy Industries state that the NOPR lacks important
details such as whether the Commission's determination is subject to
rehearing, and whether a final decision can be appealed under the FPA
to an appellate court.\859\ Solar Energy Industries state that an
adverse determination by the Commission could impose upwards of $100
million in harm on a QF, and it is unclear whether the QF would have a
path to relief if the Commission erred in its determination. Solar
Energy
[[Page 54706]]
Industries state that the current practice, where the challenger bears
the responsibility of seeking declaratory relief, strikes an
appropriate balance.\860\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\859\ Id. at 58.
\860\ Id. at 59.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
542. Several commenters, on the other hand, support the NOPR
proposal to allow a party to protest a self-certification or self-
recertification of a facility without being required to file a separate
petition for declaratory order and to pay the associated filing
fee.\861\ Several commenters argue that the proposed amendment would
strike the right balance and distribute the burdens of proof
appropriately.\862\ Several commenters also state that this proposal
would increase the efficiency of the process, reduce administrative
costs, and could solve potential certification problems before they
even begin.\863\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\861\ Alaska Power Comments at 2; Alliant Energy Comments at 22-
23; APPA Comments at 31-35; Duke Energy Comments at 23-24; Indiana
Municipal Comments at 10; NRECA Comments at 21-22; Portland General
Comments at 21-22; Ohio Commission Energy Advocate Comments at 10;
Chamber of Commerce Comments at 8; We Stand Comments at 3.
\862\ APPA Comments at 31-35; NRECA Comments at 21-22; Ohio
Commission Energy Advocate Comments at 10.
\863\ Indiana Municipal Comments at 10; NRECA Comments at 21-22;
Portland General Comments at 21-22.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
543. Other commenters support the NOPR proposal, but with caveats
or extra requests.\864\ Golden Valley recommends that the 30-day clock
to challenge QF self-certification or self-recertification begins when
the QF serves notice to the interested electric utility, not when the
QF makes its filing with the Commission.\865\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and
OSEIA state that the Commission should provide a 60-day deadline after
the filings are complete by which time a failure of the Commission to
rule results in the objection being denied by operation of law.\866\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\864\ DTE Electric Comments at 9-10; Golden Valley Electric
Comments at 1-2, 3-7; Industrial Energy Consumers Comments at 14;
Northern Laramie Range Alliance Comments at 3; NorthWestern Comments
at 17-18; ELCON Comments at 19-20, 37-38.
\865\ Golden Valley Electric Comments at 2.
\866\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 74.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
544. NorthWestern requests the QFs be subject to various discovery
requests when they self-certify or self-recertify.\867\ Two commenters
argue that any challenging party should be required to include an
affidavit from a company official.\868\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\867\ NorthWestern Comments at 17-18.
\868\ Industrial Energy Consumers Comments at 14; ELCON Comments
at 20, 38.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
545. NorthWestern and Northern Laramie Range Alliance request that
QF developers seeking certification with the Commission should be
required to publish notice in local newspapers in the states in which
the development would be located, in order to alert affected parties so
they could intervene in the certification process.\869\ El Paso
Electric is concerned by the proposal to limit the ability to challenge
QF status once it has been certified in a Commission certification
proceeding or in response to a challenge unless the new challenger can
demonstrate a change in the facility circumstances that threaten the
validity of the previous finding. El Paso Electric states that
sometimes QFs fail to provide utilities with their QF application and
so the utility does not know to protest.\870\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\869\ NorthWestern Comments at 3; Northern Laramie Range
Alliance Comments at 3.
\870\ El Paso Electric Comments at 5.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
546. Ares notes that small power production QFs could be aggregated
under the more-than-one-but-less-than-10-miles rebuttable presumption
and not even be aware of the other small power production QFs because
of a lack of information.\871\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\871\ Ares Comments at 6.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
3. Commission Determination
547. We adopt the NOPR proposal to revise 18 CFR 292.207(a) to
allow an interested person or entity to seek to intervene and to file a
protest of a self-certification or self-recertification of a QF, and
not have to file a petition for declaratory order and pay the filing
fee for petitions.\872\ We also adopt the other changes to the QF
certification process proposed in the NOPR, with the additions detailed
below. We find that any increased administrative burden or litigation
risk imposed by the new rule is justified by the need to ensure that
QFs meet the statutory criteria for QF status.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\872\ We amend the proposed regulation in the NOPR to move the
sections referring to protests and interventions from 18 CFR 292.204
to 18 CFR 292.207.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
548. The ability to intervene and to file a protest of a self-
certification or self-recertification of a QF without having to file a
petition for declaratory order and pay the filing fee for petitions is
effective as of the effective date of the final rule. However, we will
grant legacy treatment to existing QFs under certain circumstances, as
we explain below. With the exceptions noted below, protests pursuant to
this final rule will not be allowed to QF certifications and
recertifications (including self-certifications and self-
recertifications) that are submitted before the effective date of the
final rule, although entities may still challenge by filing a petition
for declaratory order and submitting the required fee. Conversely,
protests can be made to QF certifications (both self-certification and
application for Commission certification) or recertifications (both
self-recertification and application for Commission recertification)
that are submitted on or after the effective date of this final rule.
We note here that it is the date of filing for certification or
recertification, and not the date of construction, that determines
whether our new protest rule applies to the certification or
recertification.
549. Many commenters have argued for expansive legacy treatment for
recertification of existing projects. They have noted that QFs need to
recertify when property is transferred, PPAs expire, or even for non-
substantive changes, such as changes in contact information or street
address.\873\ Commenters argue that, if the new protest rules apply to
recertifications, existing QFs could lose their QF status, even if
their configuration or other relevant factors do not materially change,
when they file their recertifications, upsetting the settled
expectations under which the QFs built their facilities.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\873\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 75; Terna Energy
Comments at 1-2, 7.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
550. We agree that QF recertifications to implement or address non-
substantive changes should not be subject to our new protest rule; the
settled expectations of the QFs should be respected in such instances.
Accordingly, we find that protests may be filed to an initial
certification (both self-certification and application for Commission
certification) filed on or after the effective date of this final rule,
but only to a recertification (both self-recertification and
application for Commission recertification) that makes substantive
changes to the existing certification and that are filed on or after
the effective date of this final rule. Substantive changes that may be
subject to a protest may include, for example, a change in electrical
generating equipment that increases power production capacity by the
greater of 1 MW or 5 percent of the previously certified capacity of
the QF, or a change in ownership in which an owner increases its equity
interest by at least 10% from the equity interest previously reported.
We find that recertifications (both self-recertifications and
applications for Commission recertifications) making ``administrative
only'' changes should not be subject to
[[Page 54707]]
a protest pursuant to this final rule.\874\ We believe that excepting
from protests QF recertifications making non-substantive changes will
allow QFs to make such changes and recertify without potentially losing
their QF status.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\874\ As noted elsewhere in this final rule, our allowing
protests does not eliminate the ability to file a petition for
declaratory order seeking revocation of qualifying status.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
551. Solar Energy Industries asserts that the certification process
will no longer be quick, and estimates that it would require an
additional approximately 90 to 120 hours per year to comply with these
new requirements. Solar Energy Industries is concerned that QFs may
need to defend numerous self-certifications over a facility's lifetime,
and asserts that QFs could be forced to recertify any time the
information represented in the Form No. 556 changes.\875\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\875\ Solar Energy Industries at 57.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
552. We do not agree with Solar Energy Industries' estimates.
First, we note that 18 CFR 292.207(d) (which we are not altering in
this rule except to renumber as 18 CFR 292.207(f)) already states that
if a QF fails to conform with any material facts or representations
presented in the certification, the QF status of the facility may no
longer be relied upon,\876\ and hence it is long-standing practice that
a QF must recertify when material facts or representations in the Form
No. 556 change.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\876\ 18 CFR 292.207(d), which this final rule will renumber to
18 CFR 292.207(f).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
553. Second, certifications and recertifications are already
subject to protests, albeit in the form of petitions for declaratory
order, and therefore dealing with objections to a certification or
recertification is not new. Although the new procedures may result in
more protests being filed than the number of petitions that have been
filed, we believe that the conditions we impose in this final rule will
limit the number of protests filed. The Commission anticipates that
most, though not all, of the protests filed pursuant to the new 18 CFR
292.207(a) will relate to the new more-than-one-but-less-than-10-miles
rebuttable presumption.\877\ Such protests will necessarily be limited
because not all certifications and recertifications will be subject to
the new more-than-one-but-less-than-10-miles rebuttable presumption.
Only small power production facilities seeking QF status that have an
affiliated small power production QF more than one but less than 10
miles away and that uses the same energy resource are subject to the
rebuttable presumption. Small power production facilities that do not
have multiple small power production facilities or affiliates will not
be affected by the new rebuttable presumption. Nor will cogeneration
QFs be affected by the new rebuttable presumption.\878\ Additionally,
in general as described above, protests may only be made to an initial
certification (both self-certification and application for Commission
certification) filed on or after the effective date of this final rule,
and only to a recertification (self-recertification or application for
Commission recertification) that makes substantive changes to the
existing certification that are filed after the effective date of this
final rule.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\877\ While we anticipate that most protests will involve
interested persons or entities attempting to rebut the presumption
of separate sites for affiliated small power production qualifying
facilities that are more than one and less than 10 miles apart, we
note that protesters may also protest any fact or representation in
the Form No. 556, or other aspect of a QF's filing they believe is
inconsistent with PURPA or our PURPA Regulations.
\878\ The 80 MW limit and same site determination only apply to
small power production facilities, not cogeneration facilities. See
16 U.S.C. 796(17)(A).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
554. Third, we are also instituting time limits on protests that
may be filed under this final rule. We adopt the NOPR proposal that
interested parties will have 30 days from the date of the filing of the
Form No. 556 at the Commission to file a protest (without paying a
fee).\879\ Additionally, a protestor must concurrently serve its
protest on the Form No. 556 applicant pursuant to 18 CFR 385.2010.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\879\ We note that section 292.207(c) of the PURPA Regulations
requires the applicant to concurrently with its filing serve a copy
of the filing on each applicable electric utility as well as the
applicable State regulatory authority. We expect an applicant
seeking QF status (or recertifying its status) to timely comply with
that regulation. Therefore, a utility should also receive the filing
at the same time that the filing is made at the Commission.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
555. Fourth, regarding Solar Energy Industries' concern that a QF
may have to engage in multiple defenses of its status, in addition to
the above limits on protests, once the Commission has affirmatively
certified an applicant's QF status in response to a protest opposing a
self-certification or self-recertification, or in response to an
application for Commission certification or Commission recertification,
any later protest to a recertification (self-recertification or
application for Commission recertification) making substantive changes
to a QF's existing certification, e.g., asserting that the entity
seeking QF status is at the same site as affiliated small power
production QFs more than one but less than 10 miles from it, must
demonstrate changed circumstances from the facts on which the
Commission acted on the certification filing that call into question
the continued validity of the earlier certification.
556. Finally, even if it indeed takes some small power production
facilities an additional 90 to 120 hours (and we think that unlikely),
that is not an unreasonable burden to impose to ensure that a
generating facility that seeks to be a QF is, in fact, entitled to QF
status and complying with PURPA.\880\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\880\ The regulations adopted in this final rule explicitly make
self-certifications and self-recertifications effective upon filing
and allow them to remain effective even if challenged until such
time as the Commission finds that a facility does not qualify to be
a QF. Additionally, entities seeking QF status can file self-
certifications years in advance of facility operation, such that the
few months contemplated by the new process should not cause delay.
Finally, with regard to the time it may take to fill in the Form No.
556, we note that while an entity seeking QF status may choose to
preemptively defend against claims that it should be considered to
be at the same site as affiliated small power production qualifying
facilities located more than one but less than 10 miles from it,
this is optional, not required.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
557. Turning to the requirements for a protest, as proposed in the
NOPR, we will require any person or entity filing a protest to specify
facts that make a prima facie demonstration that the facility described
in the certification (both self-certification and application for
Commission certification) or recertification (both self-recertification
or application for Commission recertification) does not satisfy the
requirements for QF status. We will also require any protest to be
adequately supported with any supporting documents, contracts, or
affidavits, as appropriate. Just as public utilities are typically not
subject to discovery with regard to their rate filings under section
205 of the FPA prior to the Commission's instituting trial-type
evidentiary hearings,\881\ we similarly decline to make QFs subject to
discovery requests when they self-certify or self-recertify.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\881\ 18 CFR 385.401(a).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
558. The Commission also orders here that an applicant's response
to a protest will be allowed under 18 CFR 385.213(a)(2). By this final
rule, we are consistent with that regulation, ``otherwise order[ing]''
that such answers may be filed. They will be due no later than 30 days
after the filing of the protest.
559. Rooftop solar developers frequently finance the initial
development of rooftop solar photovoltaic (PV) systems of individual
homeowners, and then retain ownership of such PV systems for extended
periods of time until the ownership is
[[Page 54708]]
eventually transferred to the relevant homeowners. While these rooftop
solar PV systems are owned by the developer, each individual rooftop
solar PV system would be considered affiliated electrical generating
equipment of every other rooftop solar PV system owned by that
developer. When there are multiple co-owned rooftop solar PV systems
within a mile, and thus at the same site, they may exceed 1 MW and
therefore be required to file for certification or recertification
unless they receive a waiver.\882\ Moreover, whenever they add an
additional rooftop solar PV system to their portfolio, or alternatively
transfer the ownership of such a rooftop solar PV system to the
relevant homeowner, their facility could be viewed as no longer
conforming with the material facts in their prior certification or
recertification; thus they would need to recertify.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\882\ See Sunrun, Inc., 167 FERC ] 61,059 (2019).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
560. Due to the unique nature of rooftop solar PV developers, the
Commission finds the recertification requirement for PV developers
could be unduly burdensome. Therefore, to lessen the burden on such
developers when recertifying, we will permit rooftop solar PV
developers an alternative option to file their recertification
applications. That is, rather than be required to file for
recertification each time the rooftop solar developer adds or removes a
rooftop facility, a rooftop solar PV developer may recertify on a
quarterly basis. The filing would be due within 45 days after the end
of the calendar quarter. However, if in any quarter a rooftop solar PV
developer either has no changes or only has changes of power production
capacity of 1 MW or less, then it would not be required to recertify
until it has accumulated changes greater than 1 MW total over the
quarters since its last filing.\883\ Additionally, we note that rooftop
solar PV developers, like all small power production facilities, will
not be subject to protests when they file recertifications that are
``administrative only'' in nature, but would be subject to such
protests when they make substantive changes to the existing
certification as detailed above in this section.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\883\ For example, if a rooftop solar QF increases its power
production capacity by 0.9 MW in a quarter, it would not need to
file to recertify for that quarter. However, if in the next quarter
the rooftop solar QF increased its power production capacity by 0.9
MW, it would need to recertify for that quarter because cumulatively
over the quarters since its last filing it has changed its power
production capacity by more than 1 MW (i.e., under this example the
rooftop solar QF changed its power production capacity since its
last recertification filing by 1.8 MW).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
561. We take this opportunity to clarify that, when the Commission
issues an order revoking QF certification, such order is subject to
rehearing and appeal pursuant to the FPA.\884\ The Commission's
authority to determine whether or not a facility is a qualifying small
power production facility stems from PURPA section 201, which amended
FPA section 3 to add paragraph (17).\885\ Similarly, FPA section 3(18)
grants the Commission authority to determine whether a cogeneration
facility meets the Commission's requirements.\886\ Because the
Commission's authority is grounded in the FPA, the Commission's order
revoking QF certification is subject to rehearing and appeal pursuant
to FPA section 313.\887\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\884\ Similarly, when the Commission issues an order
affirmatively certifying an applicant's QF status (in response to a
protest opposing a self-certification or self-recertification, or in
response to an application for Commission certification or
recertification), any party to that proceeding aggrieved by the
order, including the protestant, may seek rehearing and appeal
pursuant to the FPA.
\885\ 16 U.S.C. 796(17). Section 3(17) of the FPA mandates a
size requirement for a small power production facility: It must have
``a power production capacity which, together with any other
facilities located at the same site (as determined by the
Commission), is not greater than 80 megawatts.''
\886\ 16 U.S.C. 796(18).
\887\ 16 U.S.C. 825l. The Commission has previously entertained
rehearing of an order revoking QF status, Golden Valley Elec. Ass'n,
Inc., 167 FERC ] 61,208 (2019), reh'g denied, 170 FERC ] 61,025
(2020), and of an order denying petitions to revoke QF status, N.
Laramie Range All., 138 FERC ] 61,171, reh'g denied, 139 FERC ]
61,190 (2012), appeal dismissed, 733 F.3d 1030. There have also been
appeals of orders denying petitions to revoke QF status. N. Laramie
Range All. v. FERC, 733 F.3d 1030 (10th Cir. 2013) (dismissing
appeal on other grounds); Brazos Elec. Power Coop. Inc., v. FERC,
205 F.3d 235 (5th Cir. 2000) (denying petition for review). Unlike
PURPA section 210, PURPA section 201 amends the FPA and is therefore
subject to FPA section 313. See Portland Gen. Elec. Co. v. FERC, 854
F.3d 692, 700 (2017); Midland Power Coop. v. FERC, 774 F.3d 1, 3
(2014).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
562. El Paso Electric states that sometimes the utility does not
know to protest, because sometimes QFs fail to provide utilities with
their QF application, and El Paso Electric is therefore concerned by
the Commission's proposal to limit protests by requiring that once the
Commission has affirmatively certified an applicant's QF status, any
later protest must demonstrate changed circumstances. We note that a QF
that is filing a FERC Form No. 556 is currently required by 18 CFR
292.207(c) (which we are not altering in this rule except to renumber
as 18 CFR 292.207(e)) to serve a copy on each electric utility with
which it expects to interconnect, transmit or sell electric energy to,
or purchase supplementary, standby, back-up or maintenance power from,
and the state regulatory authority of each state where the facility and
each affected utility is located. This final rule does not change that
requirement and we expect applicants to timely comply with that
regulation. Should an issue arise, though, the Commission can address
it on a case-by-case basis as the circumstances warrant. Additionally,
we note that, if a self-certification or self-recertification is not
protested within the 30 day-period permitted for protests, then, just
as it could prior to this final rule, a challenger still has the
ability to file a petition for declaratory order, with the filing fee,
without being required to show changed circumstances to do so.
563. Regarding Basin's request to allow petitions seeking de-
certification of QFs that have previously filed self-certifications and
ultimately never proceed to development,\888\ as we note above we limit
the ability to file a protest (rather than a petition for declaratory
order, with the accompanying filing fee) to within 30 days of the date
of the filing of the self-certification or self-recertification. If an
interested party would like to contest a self-certification or self-
recertification later than 30 days after the date of its filing, then
the interested party may file a petition for declaratory order with the
accompanying filing fee, just as they could prior to the effective date
of this final rule.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\888\ Basin Comments at 11.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
564. We decline to adopt the requests that QF developers seeking
certification with the Commission be required to publish notice in
local newspapers in the states in which the development would be
located. We find that the service requirement already in our
regulations cited above should serve to provide adequate notice to
affected entities.
565. We decline to impose a 60-day deadline after which a failure
of the Commission to rule on the protest results in the protest being
denied by operation of law. Self-certification will be effective upon
filing and we adopt the NOPR proposal that the self-certifications will
remain effective after a protest has been filed, until such time as the
Commission issues an order revoking certification. We also clarify that
self-recertifications will likewise remain effective after a protest
has been filed, until such time as the Commission issues an order
revoking certification.
566. We also will adopt the NOPR's proposed timeline for issuance
of an order following protests to a QF self-certification and self-
recertification. The
[[Page 54709]]
Commission will issue an order within 90 days of the filing of a
protest. However, if the Commission requests more information, the time
period for the Commission order would be extended to 60 days from the
filing of a complete answer to the information request. In addition to
any extension resulting from a request for information, the Commission
also may toll the 90-day period during which the Commission commits to
act for one additional 60-day period. We clarify, however, that, absent
Commission action by the date of the expiration of the tolling period,
a protest will be deemed denied, and the self-certification or self-
recertification will remain effective. We find that this timeline
provides both QFs and other interested persons with certainty about the
QFs' status within a reasonable amount of time.
567. Regarding Ares' concern that small power production QFs could
be aggregated under the new rule without being aware of the other small
power production QFs with which they are aggregated, the Commission
notes that this concern would only apply to small power production
facilities owned by the same person or its affiliates; it is unlikely
that the owner(s) of one facility would not be aware of other,
affiliated QFs. Furthermore, the presumption continues to be that a
small power production facility seeking QF status that is located more
than one but less than 10 miles from any affiliated small power
production QFs is at a separate site from those affiliated small power
production QFs, and the Commission here is simply making this
presumption rebuttable. If an entity challenges that presumption, the
applicant seeking QF status would necessarily be served with the
protest \889\ and thus informed of the challenge, and given the
opportunity to defend against the challenge.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\889\ 18 CFR 385.211(b).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
568. Regarding Solar Energy Industries contention regarding the
currently pending Connected Entity proceeding, that is a separate
proceeding and beyond the scope of this proceeding. Moreover, the data
collection at issue in that proceeding does not eliminate the need for
the Commission to collect the data required by the FERC Form No. 556 so
that the Commission has the information it needs to determine whether a
facility qualifies to be a QF consistent with the standards laid out in
the statute. In any event, we note that the Connected Entity rulemaking
was about market-based rate sellers, not QFs, and it is likely that the
Connected Entity rulemaking would not apply to many QFs in the first
place since they often nether seek nor have the authority to sell at
market-based rates.
569. Regarding Allco's concerns about the RFA, we discuss the RFA
issue in section VII.
F. Corresponding Changes to the FERC Form No. 556
1. NOPR Proposal
570. The Commission proposed changes to the FERC Form No. 556,
corresponding to the new rules discussed above regarding whether QFs
are at separate sites. Currently, item 8a of FERC Form No. 556 requires
that the applicant identify any facilities with electrical generating
equipment within one mile of the instant facility's electrical
generating equipment, as shown below:
[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TR02SE20.000
571. The Commission proposed adding a new item 8b,\890\ which would
be similar to the current item 8a, except that it would cover
affiliated facilities whose nearest electrical generating equipment is
greater than 1 mile and less than 10 miles from the electrical
generating equipment of the instant facility.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\890\ Subsequent items in that section of the FERC Form No. 556
would be retained but re-numbered and moved down accordingly.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
572. The Commission proposed that the instructions for the new item
8b would also allow applicants with facilities identified under item 8b
(i.e., facilities more than one mile apart and less than 10 miles
apart) to, if they choose, explain (in the Miscellaneous section
starting on page 19 of the form) why the facilities identified under
item 8b should be considered separate facilities,\891\ considering the
relevant physical and ownership factors. The Commission further
proposed to provide reference, in the instructions to the new item 8b,
to the paragraphs of this final rule which discuss the relevant
physical and ownership factors that may be asserted to defend against
rebuttal.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\891\ As discussed in detail in section IV.D.1.d, this final
rule will change the references to ``separate facilities'' or ``the
same facility'' to ``at separate sites'' or ``at the same site.''
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
573. The Commission sought comment on whether item 8a (existing)
should be revised and item 8b (as proposed) written to require that the
applicant specify the distance from the instant facility to each
affiliated facility listed. We also sought comment on whether items 8a
and (new) 8b should require the applicant to document (in the
Miscellaneous section on page 19 of the FERC Form No. 556) how the
distances reported were calculated. Specifically, we sought comment on
whether the applicant should be required to identify the particular
electrical generating equipment and associated geographic coordinates
used
[[Page 54710]]
in calculating the distance(s) between the facilities.
574. The Commission noted that item 8a currently requires
applicants to list all affiliated ``facilities.'' Under this
requirement, an applicant would have to list all affiliated QFs as well
as affiliated non-QFs. We requested comment on whether such a
requirement is more burdensome than necessary. It was not clear that
requiring the listing of affiliated non-QFs is necessary in monitoring
for compliance with the relevant QF regulations, which are concerned
only with the distance between affiliated QFs.
575. The Commission also sought comment on whether item 3c
(geographic coordinates) and the Geographic Coordinates instructions on
page 4 of the current FERC Form No. 556 should be modified such that
reporting of geographic coordinates should be required for all
applications, rather than only for applications where there is no
facility street address (as has been the case). We believed such
information may provide more transparency in measuring distances
between facilities, and that such transparency may be useful for both
the public and Commission staff in monitoring compliance with the
Commission's QF regulations.
576. The Commission noted, as it did in Order No. 732,\892\ and as
in the general form instructions on page 4 of the FERC Form No. 556,
that such coordinates can be obtained through certain free online map
services (with links and instructions available through the
Commission's QF website); GPS devices (including smartphones, which are
now nearly ubiquitous); Google Earth; property surveys; various
engineering or construction drawings; property deeds; or municipal or
county maps showing property lines. The Commission also noted that the
Commission has a link on its QF web page (https://www.ferc.gov/industries-data/electric/power-sales-and-markets/purpa-qualifying-facilities) which provides assistance with determining geographic
coordinates of facilities. As such, the Commission believed that the
burden that would be created by requiring every QF to provide
geographic coordinates would be limited. Even so, the Commission sought
comment on whether the value of the information to the public and the
Commission would outweigh the limited burden.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\892\ Revisions to Form, Procedures, and Criteria for
Certification of Qualifying Facility Status for a Small Power
Production or Cogeneration Facility, Order No. 732, 130 FERC ]
61,214, at P 100 (2010).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
2. Comments
577. A few commenters oppose the changes to FERC Form No. 556 as
proposed in the NOPR.\893\ Solar Energy Industries and the Southeast
Public Interest Organizations contend that the proposed new item 8b
that requests a list of all affiliated facilities within one to 10
miles from the certifying QF would be a significant increase in
information collection, time, effort, and cost of QF
certification.\894\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\893\ Solar Energy Industries Comments at 8; Southeast Public
Interest Organizations Comments at 36-37.
\894\ Solar Energy Industries Comments at 56; Southeast Public
Interest Organizations Comments at 36-37.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
578. The Southeast Public Interest Organizations further object
that the obligation to show how distances are calculated and to
identify electrical generating equipment and their associated
geographic coordinates are overly burdensome for facilities that are
presumed to be separate and contradicts the rebuttable presumption of
separate facilities, which usually places the burden on the
challenger.\895\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\895\ Southeast Public Interest Organizations Comments at 37-38.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
579. The Southeast Public Interest Organizations also assert it
would be reasonable to ask for only affiliated QFs and to exclude non-
QF affiliates from the questions in item 8.\896\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\896\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
580. Several commenters support changes to FERC Form No. 556 as
proposed in the NOPR.\897\ A few commenters support the proposed
changes to item 8a and proposed new item 8b and argue that the
additional information might be otherwise difficult to find and will be
useful to clarify if the assumption of separate facilities is
appropriate.\898\ Some commenters support requiring all applicants to
supply geographic coordinates in item 3c, regardless of whether they
have a street address.\899\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\897\ APPA Comments at 23; EEI Comments at 50; Portland General
Comments at 17-18; Subsurface Engineering Association Comments at 1.
\898\ APPA Comments at 23-24; EEI Comments at 50.
\899\ EEI Comments at 50; Idaho Commission Comments at 7;
Subsurface Engineering Association Comments at 1.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
581. Two commenters support the collection of information for all
affiliated facilities, not just QF affiliates, within the one or ten-
mile radius requested in item 8a and proposed item 8b, respectively,
because they believe it will be needed to identify QFs not complying
with the proposed rule.\900\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\900\ EEI Comments at 50-51; Portland General Comments at 18.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
582. Solar Energy Industries assert that the proposed item 8b to
the Form No. 556, requiring a listing of all affiliated facilities
whose nearest electrical generating equipment is greater than one mile
and less than 10 miles from the electrical generating equipment of the
certifying QF, is a substantial expansion of the information collection
requirements and goes against the Commission's previously-granted
blanket exemptions for QFs to relieve the burden of public utility
regulation. Solar Energy Industries argue that this is not a mere
information collection requirement, but a request for information that
is not otherwise publicly available and is inconsistent with the
Commission's finding on the burden of collecting Connected Entity
information. Solar Energy Industries argue that collecting such
information from QFs is unwarranted discriminatory treatment and is
arbitrary and capricious.\901\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\901\ Solar Energy Industries Comments at 56-57.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
583. A few commenters requested additional changes to FERC Form No.
556.\902\ North American-Central would like the Commission to create
separate Form No. 556 forms for small power producers and cogeneration
QFs for a more distinct and simplified application process.\903\ EEI
would like Form No. 556 to explicitly include battery storage.\904\ EEI
requests that the Form No. 556 collect information on the rated
capacity and notes that net capacity may not be the appropriate measure
of power production. Solar Energy Industries also noted that the
Commission stated in Order No. 732 that future changes to Form No. 556
would not go through a rulemaking and would instead be reviewed by the
Office of Management and Budget with a period for public comments.\905\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\902\ EEI Comments at 51; El Paso Electric Comments at 5-6;
North American-Central Comments at 7.
\903\ North American-Central Comments at 7.
\904\ EEI Comments at 51-52.
\905\ Solar Energy Industries Comments at 56.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
3. Commission Determination
584. We adopt the NOPR proposals regarding changes to the FERC Form
No. 556, with the further clarifications and additions described below.
The revised Form No. 556 will be attached to this rule in eLibrary, but
will not be published in the Federal Register or Code of Federal
Regulations. The Commission finds that the added information collected
by these changes
[[Page 54711]]
is necessary to implement the changes made to the regulations in this
final rule, and thus justifies the increase in reporting burden.
585. The currently effective Form No. 556 contains a ``Who Must
File'' section which specifies when an applicant seeking QF status or
recertification of QF status must file a self-certification, and when
such applicant is exempt from the filing requirement. We will revise
the ``Who Must File'' section to clarify that the exemption from the
requirement to complete or file a Form No. 556 applies to an applicant
seeking QF status for a small power production facility that, together
with any affiliated small power production QFs within one mile of the
entity seeking small power production QF status, has a net power
production capacity of 1 MW or less. While we did not seek comment on
this corrective change in the NOPR, this change is consistent with the
Commission's determination in SunE B9 Holdings LLC, \906\ and serves to
make the Form No. 556 more transparent in its application.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\906\ 157 FERC ] 61,044 at P 16 (``the one-mile rule of section
292.204(a)(2) is a size determination which the Commission has
consistently applied generally to the regulations pursuant to PURPA,
and which applies here to determining the applicability of the less-
than-1-MW exemption of section 292.203(d)'') (internal citations
omitted).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
586. We also revise the ``Who Must File'' section to include a
``Recertification'' section which provides the text of revised 18 CFR
292.207(f), (previously 18 CFR 292.207(d)) which states that a QF must
file for recertification whenever the QF ``fails to conform with any
material facts or representation presented . . . in its submittals to
the Commission.'' \907\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\907\ 18 CFR 292.207(d).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
This addition does not alter our recertification requirements, and
we include it here simply to make the Form No. 556 clearer in its
application.
587. The total burden estimates in the ``Paperwork Reduction Act
Notice'' section of FERC Form No. 556 will be updated based on the
changes in this final rule, to provide the following estimates: 1.5
hours for self-certifications of facilities of 1 MW or less; 1.5 hours
for self-certifications of a cogeneration facility over 1 MW; 50 hours
for applications for Commission certification of a cogeneration
facility; 3.5 hours for self-certifications of small power producers
over 1 MW and less than a mile or more than 10 miles from affiliated
small power production QFs that use the same energy resource; 56 hours
for an application for Commission certification of a small power
production facility over 1 MW and less than a mile or more than 10
miles from affiliated small power production QFs that use the same
energy resource; 9.5 hours for self-certifications of small power
producers over 1 MW with affiliated small power production QFs more
than one but less than 10 miles that use the same energy resource; 62
hours for an application for Commission certification of a small power
production facility over 1 MW with affiliated small power production
QFs more than one but less than 10 miles that use the same energy
resource.
588. We find that an explanatory ``Protest to the Filing'' section
should be added to the FERC Form No. 556 to note that, pursuant to 18
CFR 292.207, an interested person or entity has 30 days from the date
of the filing of the FERC Form No. 556 to intervene or file a protest.
The ``Protest to the Filing'' section will state that the protestor
must concurrently serve a copy of such filing, pursuant to 18 CFR
385.211(b), on the Form No. 556 applicant. The ``Protest to the
Filing'' section will also state that the Form No. 556 applicant will
have 30 days to file any answer to a protest. The ``Protest to the
Filing'' section will also state that protests may be made to any
initial certification, and any recertifications on or after the
effective date of this final rule making substantive changes to the
existing certification, which may include, for example, a change in
electrical generating equipment that increases power production
capacity by the greater of 1 MW or 10 percent of the previously
certified capacity of the QF, or a change in ownership in which an
owner increases their equity interest by at least 10% from the equity
interest previously reported. The ``Protest to the Filing'' section
will note that ``administrative only'' changes will not be subject to
protests.
589. The Commission finds that item 3c (geographic coordinates) and
the Geographic Coordinates instructions on page 4 of the current FERC
Form No. 556 will be revised to require all applicants to report the
applicant facility's geographic coordinates, rather than only for
applications where there is no street address (as was the case
previously). We find that such information will provide more
transparency regarding the location of each site, and that such
transparency may be useful for both the public and Commission staff in
monitoring compliance with the Commission's QF regulations.
590. The Commission will change item 8a, which currently requires
applicants to list all affiliated facilities within one mile, to
instead require that the applicant only list affiliated small power
production QFs using the same energy resource within one mile.
591. We modify the NOPR's proposal to add the collection of
information for affiliated facilities whose nearest electrical
generating equipment is more than one but less than 10 miles from the
electrical generating equipment of the applicant's facility to instead
add the collection of information for affiliated small power production
QFs using the same energy resource located more than one mile but less
than 10 miles from the electrical generating equipment of the
applicant's facility. However, rather than adding a separate item 8b to
the Form No. 556 specifically for such QFs, as proposed in the NOPR, we
are expanding the existing item 8a to require the applicant to list all
affiliated small power production QFs using the same energy resource
whose nearest electrical generating equipment is less than 10 miles
from the electrical generating equipment of the entity seeking small
power production QF status.
592. We determine that the revised item 8a will require the
applicant to list the geographic coordinates of the nearest
``electrical generating equipment'' of both its own facility and the
affiliated small power production QF in question based on the
definitions adopted in this final rule. The distance between the entity
seeking small power production QF status and each affiliated small
power production QF will be automatically calculated based on these
coordinates. For any affiliated small power production QFs that cannot
be described in item 8a due to space limitations, the instructions will
direct applicants to provide the required information for such small
power production QFs in the Miscellaneous section of the form. To
facilitate the uniform calculation of distances for facility data that
are entered into the Miscellaneous section of the form, a distance
calculator will be added to the form, and the form instructions will
direct applicants to use the calculator to convert their facilities'
geographic coordinates into distance.
593. The Commission also adopts the NOPR proposal to allow
applicants with affiliated small power production QFs greater than one
mile and less than 10 miles from the electrical generating equipment of
the entity seeking small power production QF status identified under
item 8a to, if they choose, explain why the affiliated small power
production QFs greater than one mile and less than 10 miles from the
nearest electrical generating equipment of the entity seeking QF status
identified
[[Page 54712]]
under item 8a should be considered to be at separate sites from the
entity seeking QF status, considering the relevant physical and
ownership factors. The instructions will provide references to the
relevant physical and ownership factors, as defined in this final rule,
that may be asserted to defend against rebuttal.
594. Regarding Solar Energy Industries' concern regarding the
expansion of the information collection requirements, we find that the
added information collected by item 8a of the Form No. 556 is necessary
to implement the changes made to the regulations in this final rule,
and thus justifies the increase in reporting burden. As noted in
section IV.E, the currently pending Connected Entity proceeding is a
separate proceeding and beyond the scope of this proceeding. Moreover,
the data collection at issue in that proceeding does not eliminate the
need for the Commission to collect the data required by the FERC Form
No. 556 so that the Commission has the information it needs to
determine whether a facility qualifies to be a QF consistent with the
standards laid out in the statute.
595. We note that these changes and any future changes to Form No.
556 will continue to be reviewed by the Office of Management and Budget
following solicitation of comments from the public, as described in
Order No. 732.\908\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\908\ Order No. 732, 130 FERC ] 61,214.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
596. We find the requests for additional changes to FERC Form No.
556 beyond the scope of this proceeding.
G. PURPA Section 210(m) Rebuttable Presumption of Nondiscriminatory
Access to Markets
1. PURPA Section 210(m) Implementation
a. NOPR Proposal
597. In 2006, when Order No. 688 was issued, the organized electric
markets had been in existence for only a few years and were not well
understood by all market participants. Now, fourteen years later, the
markets are more mature, and the mechanics of participation in such
markets are improved and better understood. Consequently, in the NOPR,
the Commission determined that small power production facilities below
20 MW should now be able to participate in such markets under most
circumstances. The Commission therefore proposed to revise 18 CFR
292.309(d) to reduce the net power production capacity level at which
the presumption of nondiscriminatory access to a market attaches for
small power production facilities, but not cogeneration facilities,
from 20 MW to 1 MW.
598. The Commission determined that, in light of the maturation of
organized electric markets, such a reduction was consistent with
Congress's intent to relieve electric utilities of their obligation to
purchase when a QF has nondiscriminatory access to competitive markets.
599. The Commission noted that, in establishing the original
presumption that QFs whose net power production capacity was 20 MW or
below lacked nondiscriminatory access to markets defined in sections
210(m)(1)(A)-(C) of PURPA, it had acknowledged that ``there is no
unique and distinct megawatt size that uniquely determines if a
generator is small.'' \909\ The Commission noted that, in using 20 MW
to separate the presumption that large QFs had nondiscriminatory access
and small QFs lacked such access, the Commission had recognized: (1)
Order No. 671's exemption for QFs that are 20 MW or smaller from
sections 205 and 206 of the FPA; and (2) Order Nos. 2006 and 2006-A's
setting 20 MW as the demarcation for different interconnection
standards between small and large generators.\910\ The NOPR stated
that, while the Commission had not (and likewise did not in the NOPR)
propose to revise the exemptions for QFs from sections 205 and 206 of
the FPA, the Commission had elsewhere taken steps to ease both
interconnection and market access for generation resources with small
capacities since it first implemented section 210(m) of PURPA.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\909\ Order No. 688-A, 119 FERC ] 61,305 at P 97.
\910\ See Order No. 688, 117 FERC ] 61,078 at P 76, order on
reh'g, Order No. 688-A, 119 FERC ] 61,305 at P 97; see also 18 CFR
292.601(c)(1) (``[S]ales of energy or capacity made by qualifying
facilities 20 MW or smaller, or made pursuant to a contract executed
on or before March 17, 2006 or made pursuant to a state regulatory
authority's implementation of section 210 the Public Utility
Regulatory Policies Act of 1978, 16 U.S.C. 824a-1, shall be exempt
from scrutiny under sections 205 and 206.''); Revised Regulations
Governing Small Power Production and Cogeneration Facilities, Order
No. 671, 114 FERC ] 61,102, at P 98, order on reh'g, Order No. 671-
A, 115 FERC ] 61,225 (2006) (establishing exemption for QFs 20 MW or
below from 205 and 206 of FPA); Standardization of Small Generator
Interconnection Agreements and Procedures, Order No. 2006, 111 FERC
] 61,220, at P 75, order on reh'g, Order No. 2006-A, 113 FERC ]
61,195 (2005), order granting clarification, Order No. 2006-B, 116
FERC ] 61,046 (2006).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
600. For example, the Commission noted that it had required public
utilities to provide a Fast-Track interconnection process for some
interconnection customers whose capacity is up to and including 5 MW
(up from the previous 2 MW threshold),\911\ and had required each RTO/
ISO to revise its tariff to include a participation model for electric
storage resources that establishes a minimum size requirement for
participation in the RTO/ISO markets that does not exceed 100 kW.\912\
While both of these changes do not apply only to generation types that
could become QFs or only to RTOs/ISOs, the Commission stated that it
believed they generally show that small power production facilities
below 20 MW, specifically those whose capacity exceeds 1 MW, now have
greater access to the markets defined in section 210(m)(1) of PURPA
than they did when the Commission first established the presumptions of
market access. The Commission also stated that, under the NOPR proposal
and like QFs over 20 MW today, small power production facilities over 1
MW would still be able to rebut the presumption of access due to
operational characteristics or transmission constraints.\913\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\911\ Small Generator Interconnection Agreements and Procedures,
Order No. 792, 145 FERC ] 61,159, at P 103 (2013), clarifying, Order
No. 792-A, 146 FERC ] 61,214 (2014).
\912\ Order No. 841, 162 FERC ] 61,127 at P 265.
\913\ See 18 CFR 292.309(c), (e), (f).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
601. The Commission did not propose to make the same reduction
applicable to cogeneration facilities. The Commission stated that,
unlike small power production facilities, which are constructed solely
to produce and sell electricity, cogeneration facilities seeking QF
certification after February 2, 2006 are statutorily required to show
that they are intended primarily to provide heat for an industrial,
commercial, residential or institutional process rather than
fundamentally for sale to an electric utility.\914\ Consequently, the
production and sale of electricity is a byproduct of these thermal
processes, and owners of cogeneration facilities might not be as
familiar with energy markets and the technical requirements for such
sales. The Commission stated that retention of the existing 20 MW level
for the presumption of access to markets therefore would be appropriate
for cogeneration facilities.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\914\ See 16 U.S.C. 824a-3(n); 18 CFR 292.205(d)(3). We
recognize that cogeneration facilities seeking certification 5 MW or
smaller after February 2, 2006 are presumed to satisfy this
requirement. 18 CFR 292.205(d)(4).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
b. Comments in Opposition
602. Numerous commenters oppose the NOPR proposal to revise 18 CFR
292.309(d) to reduce the net power production capacity level at which
the presumption of nondiscriminatory
[[Page 54713]]
access to a market attaches for small power production facilities, but
not cogeneration facilities, from 20 MW to 1 MW.\915\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\915\ Allco Comments at 2, 17-19; Advanced Energy Economy
Comments at 1-12; AllEarth Comments at 2; Biogas Comments at 2-3;
Biological Diversity Comments at 8-9; California Commission Comments
at 31-33; CARE Comments at 5-6; Con Edison Comments at 5; Covanta
Comments at 10-12; DC Commission Comments at 4-5; Distributed Sun
Comments at 2-3; ELCON Comments at 18, 31-35; Energy Recovery
Comments at 4-5; ENGIE Comments at 3-4; Commissioner Slaughter
Comments at 2, 4; Green Power Comments at 3; Industrial Energy
Consumers Comments at 6-10; Massachusetts AG Comments at 6-8;
Michigan Commission Comments at 6-7; North American-Central at 2-4;
One Energy Comments at 2; South Dakota Commission Comments at 5;
Solar Energy Industries Comments at 44-51; State Entities Comments
at 5-6; Western Resource Councils Comments at 1-144.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
i. Insufficient Evidentiary Support
603. Several commenters argue that the record does not support the
proposal.\916\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\916\ AllEarth Comments at 2; Advanced Energy Economy Comments
at 5-9; Biological Diversity Comments at 9; ELCON Comments at 31-32;
Industrial Energy Consumers Comments at 8; New England Hydropower
Comments at 11-12; NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 77;
Public Interest Organizations Comments at 76-78; SC Solar Alliance
Comments at 12; Solar Energy Industries Comments at 45-48; Southeast
Public Interest Organization Comments at 39-40.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
604. Advanced Energy Economy asserts that, when an agency reverses
course on a policy issue, and the ``new policy rests upon factual
findings that contradict those which underlay'' the previous policy,
then the agency must ``provide a more detailed justification than what
would suffice for new policy created on a blank slate.'' \917\ Advanced
Energy Economy argues that the NOPR falls short of that standard.\918\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\917\ Advanced Energy Economy Comments at 6 (citing FCC v. Fox
Television Stations, Inc., 556 U.S. at 515).
\918\ Id. at 7.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
605. Public Interest Organizations and NIPPC, CREA, REC and OSEI
argue that the Commission fails to cite any evidence supporting the
premise that the markets are more mature, and that the mechanics of
participation in such markets are improved and better understood.
Public Interest Organizations and NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA state
that the Commission asserts that QFs smaller than 20 MW can now
participate in markets on a nondiscriminatory basis ``under most
circumstances,'' but that the Commission does not explain what those
``circumstances'' are, or whether they apply as a general matter to
most small QFs.\919\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\919\ Public Interest Organizations Comments at 78; NIPPC, CREA,
REC, and OSEIA Comments at 77 (citing NOPR, 168 FERC ] 61,184 at P
126).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
606. Several commenters state that, in Order No. 688-A, the
Commission, rejected utility proposals to set the threshold at 1 MW,
and confirmed that 20 MW was an appropriate threshold.\920\ Advanced
Energy Economy states that the Commission's explanation in Order No.
688-A, which stated that the rebuttable presumptions were based on the
Commission's experience of implementing non-discriminatory open access
transmission over the past 11 years, dealing with QF issues over the
past 29 years and its experience with RTO/ISO markets for almost 10
years, contradicts the Commission's justification in the NOPR of
limited experience with organized electric markets.\921\ Advanced
Energy Economy and Southeast Public Interest Organizations assert that,
since Order No. 688, the Commission has repeatedly found that utilities
in organized markets have failed to rebut the presumption of
nondiscriminatory access to QFs, instead finding that QFs 20 MW and
under do not have sufficient access.\922\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\920\ Advanced Energy Economy Comments at 5-6; ELCON Comments at
31-32.
\921\ Advanced Energy Economy Comments at 8-9.
\922\ Id. (citing, e.g., PPL Elec. Utils Corp., 145 FERC ]
61,053, at P 24 (2013); City of Burlington, 145 FERC ] 61,121, at P
36 (2013); Fitchburg Gas and Elec. Light Co., 146 FERC ] 61,186, at
PP 32-33 (2014); Va. Elec. & Power Co., 151 FERC ] 61,038, at P 21
(2015); N. States Power Co., 151 FERC ] 61,110 (2015)); Southeast
Public Interest Organizations Comments at 39-40.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
607. Public Interest Organizations and NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA
argue that the Commission fails to explain the relevance of its Fast-
Track interconnection process or energy storage order or which barriers
these developments alleviate for small QFs' access to markets.\923\
Advanced Energy Economy asserts that the expansion of the Fast-Track
procedures only applied to a narrow slice of inverter-based resources
under 20 MW and is insufficient to support a rebuttable presumption
that all QFs under 20 MW have nondiscriminatory access.\924\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\923\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA at 77; Public Interest
Organizations Comments at 78 (citing Motor Vehicle Mfrs. Ass'n of
U.S., Inc. v. State Farm Mut. Auto. Ins. Co., 463 U.S. 29, 43 (1983)
(explaining that an agency's failure to consider the relevant
factors and supply a ``rational connection between the facts found
and the choice made'' renders its decision arbitrary and
capricious)).
\924\ Advanced Energy Comments at 7-8.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
608. Solar Energy Industries and New England Hydro argue that, just
because some small QFs participate in energy markets, that is not
sufficient justification to find that all small QFs meet the statutory
standard required for granting waiver for all QFs 20 MW or less.\925\
Public Interest Organizations assert that proper implementation of
section 210(m) requires that exemption from the mandatory purchase
obligation only applies where QF development will be stimulated by
market forces; otherwise Congress intended QF development to continue
to be encouraged by the mandatory purchase obligation.\926\ Protesters
assert that the record does not provide evidence that could reasonably
allow the Commission to conclude that small QF development will be
stimulated by market forces. On the contrary, the Public Interest
Organizations assert that the Commission's proposal placing the burden
on small QFs to rebut the presumption of access is itself a barrier to
QF development.\927\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\925\ Solar Energy Industries Comments at 46; New England Hydro
Comments at 11-12.
\926\ Public Interest Organizations Comments at 76 (citing New
PURPA Section 210(m) Regulations Applicable to Small Power
Production and Cogeneration Facilities, Order No. 688, 117 FERC ]
61,078, at P 6 (2006), order on reh'g, Order No. 688-A, 119 FERC ]
61,305 (2007), aff'd sub nom. Am. Forest and Paper Ass'n v. FERC,
550 F.3d 1179).
\927\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
609. Solar Energy Industries argue that, along with the energy
markets, the capacity markets in the RTO/ISO regions have not evolved
to provide a meaningful opportunity for any QF to sell long-term
capacity.\928\ Solar Energy Industries argue that PURPA section 210(m)
requires the Commission to find that a QF has nondiscriminatory access
to a market for long-term sales of capacity prior to relieving the
purchase obligation. Solar Energy Industries provide several examples
such as MISO's Planning Resources Auction that only provides a one-year
purchase agreement, PJM not purchasing capacity since the Commission's
July 2019 Order, and that SPP does not have a centralized capacity
market. Solar Energy Industries argue that without a specific finding
that RTO/ISO markets provide QFs with an opportunity to sell long-term
capacity, the Commission is statutorily required to maintain utilities'
obligation to purchase output from QFs 20 MWs or less.\929\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\928\ Solar Energy Industries Comments at 45.
\929\ Id. at 49.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
610. Mr. Mattson asserts, without elaboration, that FPA sections
205 and 206 disallow the Commission from lowering the nondiscriminatory
access threshold from 20 MW to 1 MW, and, therefore, claims it would
amount to a violation of state-jurisdictional rights and a taking of
property.\930\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\930\ Mr. Mattson Comments at 10.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
ii. Administrative Burden and Complex Market Rules
611. The DC Commission state that QFs 20 MW or less lack the
capability
[[Page 54714]]
to participate in a complicated wholesale market such as PJM where
there is a need to understand membership obligations and rules in order
to appropriately execute transactions.\931\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\931\ DC Commission Comments at 4-5.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
612. Allco argues that, in retail choice states, PURPA is the only
way small QFs can sell to utilities. Allco asserts that in retail
choice states there is a shifting retail customer base, therefore
utilities want obligations reduced and contracts limited to a year.
Allco asserts that utilities and state commissions cannot limit
contracts due to a potentially disappearing customer base and then
argue that a sufficient wholesale market exists for long-term sales of
electric energy and capacity to support nondiscriminatory access for
small QFs under 20 MW.\932\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\932\ Allco Comments at 18.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
613. Public Interest Organizations argue that giving special
exemptions to cogeneration facilities is discriminatory against small
power producer QFs.\933\ Two commenters also assert that small QFs are
at an inherent disadvantage compared to larger QFs because smaller QFs
are often engaged in other business enterprises, such as governmental
units distributing irrigation water or local companies unfamiliar with
energy markets.\934\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\933\ Public Interest Organizations Comments at 74.
\934\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 18-19, 24-25; Mr.
Mattson Comments at 15.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
c. Comments in Support
614. Numerous commenters support the proposal to revise 18 CFR
292.309(d) for small power production facilities but not cogeneration
facilities, to reduce the net power production capacity level at which
the presumption of nondiscriminatory access to a market applies from 20
MW to 1 MW.\935\ DTE Electric argues that RTO/ISOs can now provide
smaller resources non-discriminatory access, and therefore electric
utilities should no longer be required to purchase electric energy from
them.\936\ EEI supports the proposal because resource diversity has
improved and markets have evolved as smaller resources, including QFs,
are increasingly participating in the RTO/ISO markets. RTOs/ISOs have
also increasingly adjusted their bidding rules, forecasts, and
operations to better accommodate variable resources.\937\ Alliant and
the Ohio Commission Energy Advocate state that small resources have
increased access to wholesale markets and that RTO/ISO rule flexibility
allows for the non-discriminatory participation of very small resources
and the aggregation of even smaller resources in the markets, therefore
the 20 MW threshold is no longer appropriate.\938\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\935\ Alliant Energy Comments at 13-16; Tax Reform Comments at
2; APPA Comments at 24-26; Arizona Public Service Comments at 8-10;
Basin Comments at 12-13; Freedom Center Comments at 2; Colorado
Independent Energy Comments at 14; Connecticut Commission Comments
at 21-22; Conservative Action Comments at 2; Consumers Alliance
Comments at 1-2; Consumers Energy Comments at 4-5; DTE Electric
Comments at 4-5; East Kentucky Comments at 3; East River Comments at
2; EEI Comments 54-59; FirstEnergy Comments at 2-3; Idaho Power
comments at 14; Indiana Municipal Comments at 6-9; Institute for
Energy Research Comments at 2; Kentucky Commission Comments at 8;
Missouri River Energy Comments at 3-4; NorthWestern at 14; TAPS
Comments at 4; Ohio Commission Energy Advocate Comments at 8;
Taxpayers Protection Alliance Comments at 2; Chamber of Commerce
Comments at 7; We Stand Comments at 1-144; Taxpayer Protection
Alliance Comments at 2; TAPS Comments at 4.
\936\ DTE Electric Comments at 5-6.
\937\ EEI Comments at 56-58.
\938\ Alliant Energy Comments at 13-14; Ohio Commission Energy
Advocate Comments at 7-8.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
615. Consumer Alliance and EEI argue that reducing the threshold
will reduce costs to customers because currently some QFs with access
to markets are foregoing the opportunity to participate in those
markets and electing to contract with electric utilities under state-
implemented PURPA programs, which EEI argues compensate QFs at an
above-market rate.\939\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\939\ EEI Comments at 58-59; Consumers Alliance Comments at 1-2.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
616. The Ohio Commission Energy Advocate argues that the rebuttable
presumption process for QFs provides an appropriate safety valve for
the lower threshold.\940\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\940\ Ohio Commission Energy Advocate Comments at 8.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
d. Comments Requesting Modifications/Clarifications
617. Institute for Energy Research requests that the Commission
expand the rebuttable presumption of non-discriminatory access to QFs 1
MW and below if the market structure in a given state is appropriate.
Institute for Energy Research gives the example of Texas's open market
model, where generation is open to all comers of all sizes. Institute
for Energy Research also suggests that the Commission should include
some threshold now such that when other states achieve similar open
access market designs QFs 1 MW and below could be rebuttably presumed
to have non-discriminatory access to those markets, without the need to
undertake, at that time, a separate rulemaking on QFs 1 MW and
below.\941\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\941\ Institute of Energy Research Comments at 2.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
618. The Connecticut Commission suggests reducing the threshold at
which the presumption of nondiscriminatory access attaches to 0 MW
because the markets are more mature, the mechanics of participating in
the markets are improved and the law requires nondiscriminatory access
to the markets for all resources.\942\ Missouri River Energy recommends
lowering the threshold to 500 kW.\943\ FirstEnergy recommends the
Commission treat both small power production resources and cogeneration
resources consistently by lowering the rebuttable presumption threshold
from 20 MW to 1 MW for all QFs.\944\ Indiana Municipal requests that
the Commission automatically apply the 1 MW threshold to utilities that
have already been granted waiver for QFs over 20 MW to promote the
efficient use of the Commission's resources and savings to
utilities.\945\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\942\ Connecticut Commission Comments at 21-23.
\943\ Missouri River Energy Comments at 3.
\944\ FirstEnergy Comments at 2-3.
\945\ Indiana Municipal Comments at 8-9.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
619. The Michigan Commission requests clarification on the NOPR
proposal specifically regarding: (1) How existing contracts with QFs
greater than 1 MW but below 20 MWs are to be treated under the NOPR,
and if they would be subject to early termination or would be granted
legacy treatment indefinitely or until the end of the existing contract
term; (2) whether utilities that have already received relief from the
mandatory purchase obligation from the Commission for operating within
the footprint of an organized wholesale electricity market
automatically qualify for relief under the 1 MW threshold; and (3) how
interconnection requirements would be considered for QFs between 1 MW
and 20 MWs--specifically whether these projects would need to
interconnect at transmission level voltages to be considered as having
access to the wholesale electricity market.\946\ The Michigan
Commission notes that there is some tension between the proposal and
the market rules for MISO and PJM.\947\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\946\ Michigan Commission Comments at 6-7
\947\ Id. at 7 (commenting that MISO, for example, utilizes a 5
MW threshold as the cut off point for Network Modeling purposes and
that resources less than 5 MW are modeled on a case-by-case basis
only).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
620. Several commenters request that the Commission expand the
exemption for cogeneration to small power QFs whose primary purpose is
to self-supply but still rely on PURPA when making occasional sales to
the interconnected utility when QF output exceeds on-site
consumption.\948\ Industrial Energy
[[Page 54715]]
Consumers suggest that small power producers seeking a 20 MW self-
supply exemption meet the ``fundamental use test'' which currently
applies to cogeneration facilities.\949\ Other commenters assert that
behind-the-meter distributed energy resources,\950\ Waste to Energy
resources,\951\ and baseload renewables \952\ are similar to
cogeneration facilities and should be included in the exemption.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\948\ ELCON Comments at 32-33; Industrial Energy Consumers
Comments at 6-8; Chamber of Commerce Comments at 7.
\949\ Industrial Energy Consumers Comments at 9-10.
\950\ One Energy Comments at 2.
\951\ Industrial Energy Consumers Comments at 9-10.
\952\ Renewable Baseload Coalition Comments at 2.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
621. Public Interest Organizations request that the Commission
clarify that utilities are required to petition to eliminate the must-
purchase obligation for small QFs, even for those utilities that have
previously made such a showing for QFs larger than 20 MW.\953\ NRECA,
concerned over a potential change in aggregation for distributed energy
resources in RTOs/ISOs, requests that the Commission clarify that the
presumption will only apply to those facilities having sufficient
transmission access to the RTO/ISO markets.\954\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\953\ Public Interest Organizations Comments at 76.
\954\ NRECA Comments at 18-19.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
622. Hydropower Association asserts that, despite their potential,
hydropower resources do not receive the same tax treatment and
eligibility for state RPSs and therefore have not enjoyed the same
growth rate as other renewable energy small power producers. Hydropower
Association urges the Commission to retain the 20 MW rebuttable
presumption for hydropower resources, as would be the case for
cogenerators, because hydropower resources are required by the FPA
section 10(a) to be best adapted for comprehensive uses, including non-
power generation purposes such as irrigation, flood control,
navigation, recreation, environmental restoration, and wildlife
preservation. Hydropower Association states that non-powered dams by
definition were not constructed to generate power. Because power
generation is therefore a secondary use of these facilities, Hydropower
Association asserts that subjecting these facilities to new avoided
cost calculations will necessarily burden hydropower resources more
than other small power production facilities. Hydropower Association
also asserts that there is almost 5 GW of potential non-power dams that
could be developed and that the 20 MW exemption should be retained for
these resources.\955\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\955\ Hydropower Association Comments at 2-7 (citing 16 U.S.C.
803).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
623. Ohio Consumers Counsel states that lowering the rebuttable
presumption could permit electric utilities and state policies to deny
QFs and distributed energy resources under 20 MW from having
unrestricted and nondiscriminatory access to wholesale markets. For
example, Ohio Consumers Counsel states that the NOPR would permit
electric distribution utilities to limit the availability of after-the-
meter generation and storage from PJM's markets, such as through
restrictive net metering requirements, unreasonably low compensation
for distributed energy resources, or other state regulatory and policy
restrictions. Ohio Consumers Counsel urges the Commission to require
that investor-owned electric distribution utilities demonstrate that
they have not restricted market access to QFs and distributed energy
resources rated between 1 MW and 20 MW.\956\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\956\ Ohio Consumers Counsel Comments at 2-5.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
e. Commission Determination
624. We agree with commenters that, in Order Nos. 688 and 688-A,
given conditions at the time, the Commission established the rebuttable
presumption at QFs 20 MW or less. Furthermore, as commenters noted in
reviewing several individual cases in 2013-2015, the Commission
continued to find that those individual small power production
facilities 20 MW or less still needed the additional protections and
encouragement.\957\ However, since Order Nos. 688 and 688-A the
Commission has recognized multiple examples of small power production
facilities under 20 MW participating in RTO/ISO energy markets. The
Commission found that the electric utilities in those proceedings
rebutted the presumption of no market access and therefore terminated
the mandatory purchase obligation.\958\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\957\ PPL Elec. Utilities Corp., 145 FERC ] 61,053 at P 24; Va.
Elec. & Power Co., 151 FERC ] 61,038, at P 21; N. States Power Co.,
151 FERC ] 61,110.
\958\ See, e.g., Fitchburg Gas and Elec. Light Co., 146 FERC ]
61,186, at P 33 (2014); City of Burlington, Vt., 145 FERC ] 61,121,
at P 33 (2013).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
625. We adopt the proposal to revise 18 CFR 292.309(d) to reduce
the net power production capacity level at which the presumption of
nondiscriminatory access to a market attaches for small power
production facilities, but not for cogeneration facilities. However,
recognizing some of the challenges that QFs near 1 MW have in
participating in such markets that have been identified by commenters,
in this final rule we lower the rebuttable presumption from 20 MW to 5
MW, rather than from 20 MW to 1 MW as proposed in the NOPR. Under the
final rule, small power production facilities with a net power
production capacity at or below 5 MW will be presumed not to have
nondiscriminatory access to markets, and, conversely, small power
production facilities with a net power production capacity over 5 MW
will be presumed to have nondiscriminatory access to markets.
626. A number of commenters oppose the reduction below 20 MW,
arguing the lack of a record to support the proposal. We disagree. In
Order Nos. 688 and 688-A, the Commission determined that small QFs may
not have nondiscriminatory access to wholesale markets and, therefore,
it was reasonable to establish a presumption for small QFs. At that
time, the Commission found that it was ``reasonable and
administratively workable'' to define ``small'' for purposes of this
regulation to be QFs below 20 MW.\959\ We also note that a number of
commenters, including state entities which are charged with applying
PURPA in their jurisdictions,\960\ supported a reduction in the 20 MW
threshold.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\959\ See Order No. 688, 117 FERC ] 61,078 at PP 74-78
(establishing rebuttable presumption); Order No. 688-A, 119 FERC ]
61,305 at P 95 (``There is no perfect bright line that can be drawn
and we have reasonably exercised our discretion in adopting a 20 MW
or below demarcation for purposes of determining which QFs are
unlikely to have nondiscriminatory access to markets.'').
\960\ See Connecticut Commission Comments at 20-21; Kentucky
Commission Comments at 8.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
627. The Commission acknowledged that there is no unique number to
draw a line for determining what is a small entity.\961\ In
establishing 20 MW presumption as the line between large and small QFs
for purposes of section 210(m), the Commission looked at other non-QF
rulemaking orders in which it considered what was a small entity and
those orders showed 20 MW was a reasonable number at which to draw the
line.\962\ But, as explained below, the Commission has since
determined, based on changed circumstances since the issuance of Order
Nos. 688 and 688-A, that entities with capacity lower than 20 MW have
nondiscriminatory access to the markets and, therefore, capacity
[[Page 54716]]
level of 20 MW may no longer be a reasonable place to establish the
presumption on what constitutes a smaller entity under our regulations.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\961\ Order No. 688-A, 119 FERC ] 61,305 at P 97 (``Although
there is no unique and distinct megawatt size that uniquely
determines if a generator is small, in other contexts the Commission
has used 20 MW, based on similar considerations to those presented
here, to determine the applicability of its rules and policies.'').
\962\ See Order No. 688, 117 FERC ] 61,078 at P 76; Order No.
688-A, 119 FERC ] 61,305 at PP 96-97.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
628. Similar to our analysis in Order No. 688, we have determined
that entities below 20 MW now can participate in RTO/ISO markets.\963\
Here, we are updating the rebuttable presumption based on industry
changes since Order No. 688. Moreover, it is reasonable to update the
rebuttable presumption as markets defined in PURPA section
210(m)(1)(A), (B), and (C) evolve because that statute itself does not
establish a presumption and we are updating the rules, as PURPA
provides we will do from time to time, to ensure we comply with PURPA.
However, because the revised presumption established in this final rule
is a rebuttable presumption, QFs can seek to overcome it.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\963\ In fact, when the Commission established the rebuttable
presumption of 20 MW, commenters in that proceeding cited instances
where QFs at 1 MW or above had already had nondiscriminatory access
to RTOs/ISOs. See Order No. 688, 117 FERC ] 61,078 at PP 64-66.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
629. Over the last 15 years, the RTO/ISO markets have matured,
market participants have gained a better understanding of the mechanics
of such markets, and, as a result, we find that it is reasonable to
presume that access to the RTO/ISO markets has improved and that it is
appropriate to update the presumption for smaller production
facilities. As we did in Order No. 688, we have looked to indicia in
other orders to determine where the presumption should be set.
630. We find that at this time, market rules are inclusive of power
producers below 20 MW participating in markets. For example, since the
issuance of Order No. 688, the Commission has required public utilities
to increase the availability of a Fast-Track interconnection process
for projects up to 5 MW.\964\ That the Commission chose a 5 MW cut-off
for eligibility for the fast-track procedures represents an implicit
judgment by the Commission that facilities larger than 5 MW do not need
such procedures to be able to interconnect to the grid.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\964\ Order No. 792, 145 FERC ] 61,159, at P 103, clarified,
Order No. 792-A, 146 FERC ] 61,214.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
631. While the existence of Fast-Track interconnection processes
does not on its own demonstrate nondiscriminatory access for resources
under 20 MW, it does indicate that entities smaller than 20 MW have
access to the market. Presuming that QFs above 5 MW have such access is
therefore a reasonable approach to identifying a capacity level at
which to update the rebuttable presumption of nondiscriminatory market
access.
632. Additionally, since the issuance of Order No. 688 the
Commission has required each RTO/ISO to update its tariff to include a
participation model for electric storage resources that established a
minimum size requirement for participation in the RTO/ISO markets that
does not exceed 100 kW.\965\ These proposals require RTO/ISOs to revise
their tariffs to provide easier access for smaller resources. Requiring
markets to accommodate storage resources to as low as 100 kW also
supports that resources smaller than 20 MW have nondiscriminatory
access to those RTO/ISO markets. The Commission believes that these
developments support updating the 20 MW presumption to a lower number.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\965\ Order No. 841, 162 FERC ] 61,127 at P 265.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
633. Commenters argue that individually each of these changes in
circumstances, standing alone, may not support the reduction of the
threshold below 20 MW. But when the changes are viewed together, we
find that their cumulative effect demonstrates that it is reasonable
for the Commission to maintain a small entity rule but update its
determination of what is a small entity under this presumption under
the PURPA regulations. Additionally, the prospect of increased
participation of distributed energy resources in energy markets further
supports the proposition that wholesale markets are accommodating
resources with smaller capacities.\966\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\966\ See, e.g., Elec. Participation in Mkts Operated by Reg'l
Transmission Orgs and Independent Sys. Operators, 157 FERC ] 61,121,
P 129 (2016) (``The costs of distributed energy resources have
decreased significantly, which when paired with alternative revenue
streams and innovative financing solutions, is increasing these
resources' potential to compete in and deliver value to the
organized wholesale electric markets.'' (footnote omitted)).]
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
634. The Commission recognizes that certain of these precedents
would support reducing the presumption below 5 MW, and perhaps even
lower than 1 MW. However, the Commission has carefully considered the
comments detailing the problems that QFs have had in participating in
RTO/ISO markets, problems that necessarily are more acute for smaller
QFs at or near the 1 MW threshold proposed in the NOPR.\967\ The
Commission therefore has determined that a 5 MW is a more reasonable
threshold of non-discriminatory access to RTO/ISO markets.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\967\ See, e.g., Allco Comments at 17-19; Advanced Energy
Economy Comments at 10-11; DC Commission Comments at 5; Public
Interest Organizations Comments at 89-90; SEIA Comments at 45-49.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
635. Based on the foregoing, we find it reasonable to update the
presumption under these regulations as to what constitutes a small
entity that has non-discriminatory access to RTO/ISO markets and
markets of comparable competitive quality below 20 MW, and that 5 MW
represents a reasonable new threshold that accounts for the change of
circumstances indicating that 20 MW no longer is appropriate but also
accommodates commenters' concerns that a 1 MW threshold would be too
low. We acknowledge that ``there is no unique and distinct megawatt
size that uniquely determines if a generator is small.'' \968\ We find
that a 5 MW threshold accords with PURPA's mandate to encourage small
power production facilities, recognizes the progress made in wholesale
markets as discussed above, and balances the competing claims of those
seeking a lower threshold and those seeking a higher threshold.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\968\ Order No. 688-A, 119 FERC ] 61,305 at P 97.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
636. Individual small power production QFs that are over 5 MW and
less than 20 MW can seek to make the case, however, that they do not
truly have nondiscriminatory access to a market and should still be
entitled to a mandatory purchase obligation.
637. Regarding Advanced Energy Economy's argument that the
Commission failed to sufficiently justify its change in policy, we
disagree.\969\ In FCC v. Fox Television, the court stated that, when an
agency makes a change in policy, the agency must show that there are
good reasons for the change, ``[b]ut it need not demonstrate to a
court's satisfaction that the reasons for the new policy are better
than the reasons for the old one; it suffices that the new policy is
permissible under the statute, that there are good reasons for it, and
that the agency believes it to be better, which the conscious change of
course adequately indicates.'' \970\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\969\ Advanced Energy Economy Comments at 6 (citing FCC v. Fox
Television, 556 U.S. at 515).
\970\ FCC v. Fox Television, 556 U.S. at 515.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
638. To be clear, we are maintaining our determination from Order
No. 688 that small entities potentially may not have non-discriminatory
access for purposes of PURPA section 210(m). However, as explained
above, the Commission has determined that using 20 MW as an indicator
of what constitutes a small entity is no longer valid. Entities below
20 MW increasingly have access to the markets, become familiar with
practices and procedures, and that markets have since
[[Page 54717]]
implemented several changes to provide easier access to smaller
facilities, including small power production QFs, storage facilities,
and distributed energy resources. These changes demonstrate a change in
facts since the time we issued Order No. 688 which supports our
updating of what constitutes a small entity for purposes of PURPA
section 210(m).
639. Accordingly, we decline to adopt Ohio Consumers Counsel's
suggestion that electric utilities continue to have the burden to
demonstrate that certain small power production QFs under 20 MW have
nondiscriminatory access to markets like PJM before being relieved of
the mandatory purchase obligation for such QFs.
640. While we find that it is reasonable to update the rebuttable
presumption from 20 MW to 5 MW, we recognize commenters' concerns
regarding specific barriers to participation in RTO markets that may
affect the nondiscriminatory access to those markets of some individual
small power production facilities between 5 MW and 20 MW.
To address these concerns, we additionally are revising 18 CFR
292.309(c)(2)(i)-(vi) to include factors that small power production
facilities between 5 MW and 20 MW can point to in seeking to rebut the
presumption that they have nondiscriminatory access. These factors are
in addition to the existing ability, pursuant to 18 CFR 292.309(c), to
rebut the presumption of access to the market by demonstrating, inter
alia, operational characteristics or transmission constraints.
641. Specifically, the Commission adds to 18 CFR 292.309(c) the
following five factors: (1) Specific barriers to connecting to the
interstate transmission grid, such as excessively high costs and
pancaked delivery rates; (2) the unique circumstances impacting the
time/length of interconnection studies/queue to process small power QF
interconnection requests; (3) a lack of affiliation with entities that
participate in RTO/ISO markets; (4) a predominant purpose other than
selling electricity which would warrant the small power QF being
treated similarly to cogenerators (e.g., municipal solid waste
facilities, biogas facilities, run-of-river hydro facilities, and non-
powered dams); (5) the QF has certain operational characteristics that
effectively prevent the qualifying facility's participation in a
market; and (6) the QF lacks access to markets due to transmission
constraints, including that it is located in an area where persistent
transmission constraints in effect cause the QF not to have access to
markets outside a persistently congested area to sell the QF output or
capacity. This is not intended to be an exhaustive list of the factors
that a QF could rely upon in seeking to rebut the presumption. These
factors, among other indicia of lack of nondiscriminatory access, will
be assessed by the Commission on a case-by-case basis in considering a
claim that the presumption of nondiscriminatory access to the defined
markets should be considered rebutted for a specific QF.
642. The addition of these factors addresses commenters' concern
that not all small power production facilities between 5 and 20 MW may
have nondiscriminatory access to competitive markets, and facilitates
the ability of small power production facilities facing barriers to
participation in RTO markets to demonstrate their lack of access. For
example, while a small power production facility between 5 MW and 20 MW
does not need to be physically interconnected to transmission
facilities to be considered as having access to the statutorily-defined
wholesale electricity markets, we recognize there are some small power
production facilities between 5 MW and 20 MW that may face additional
barriers, such as excessively high costs and pancaked delivery rates,
to access wholesale markets.
643. For example, several commenters express concern over the
resources or administrative burden for some small power QFs that lack
the necessary experience or expertise to participate in energy markets.
Recognizing these concerns, we have added consideration of both the
fact that some small power production facilities will face additional
difficulties due to costs, administrative burdens, length of the
interconnection study process and the size of the queues, and the fact
that some small power production QFs do not have access to the
expertise of affiliated entities.
644. We agree with commenters that some small power production
facilities are similar to cogeneration facilities because their
predominant purpose is not power production. Like cogeneration
facilities, the sale of electricity from these small power production
facilities is a byproduct of another purpose and these facilities might
not be as familiar with energy markets and the technical requirements
for such sales. Therefore, we will allow the small subset of small
power production facilities that are between 20 MW and 5 MW to rebut
the presumption of access to markets where the predominant purpose of
the facility is other than selling electricity, and the sale of
electricity is simply a byproduct of that purpose. Finally, like all
QFs over 20 MW, we recognize that there may be particular small power
production facilities with certain operational characteristics or that
are located in an area where persistent transmission constraints in
effect cause the QF not to have access to markets outside a
persistently congested area to sell the QF output or capacity.
645. While we appreciate Indiana Municipals' concern over
preserving Commission resources, we will deny its request to
automatically apply the lower threshold to utilities that have already
been granted termination for QFs over the 20 MW threshold. We find that
it is appropriate to require utilities that were previously granted
termination of the mandatory purchase obligation for new contracts and
obligations for QFs above 20 MW, but are now seeking to terminate the
mandatory purchase obligation for new contracts and obligations for
small power production facilities between 5 and 20 MW to follow the
procedures in 18 CFR 292.310, including procedures for providing notice
to those potentially affected QFs within their footprint. That is,
those utilities for which the Commission has already granted relief
from the mandatory purchase obligation for small power production
facilities over 20 MW must reapply with the Commission requesting
relief from the mandatory purchase obligation for small power
production facilities between 5 MW and 20 MW.
646. Among other factors, the regulation's notice provision
mentioned above will allow small power production facilities between 5
MW and 20 MW an opportunity, if applicable, to present evidence that
their facility does not have nondiscriminatory access to defined
markets based on the factors discussed above.\971\ In the proceeding in
which the utility seeks to terminate the mandatory purchase obligation
between 5 MW and 20 MW, we will not entertain arguments that the
utility should lose its previously granted termination of purchase
obligation at 20 MW and above; our regulations provide how a mandatory
purchase obligation can be reinstated. We do not, in this final rule,
change a QF's right to seek reinstatement of the mandatory purchase
obligation where the conditions set forth in 18 CFR 292.309(a), (b), or
(c) are no longer met.\972\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\971\ 18 CFR 292.310.
\972\ See 18 CFR 292.311.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
647. Regarding the Michigan Commission's questions, this final rule
[[Page 54718]]
preserves the rights or remedies of any party under existing contracts
or obligations, in effect or pending approval before the appropriate
state regulatory authority or non-regulated electric utility on or
before December 31, 2020 with QFs between 5 MW and 20 MW. Consistent
with Commission precedent, this final rule defines the term
``obligations'' broadly to encompass any existing legally enforceable
obligation.\973\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\973\ See Cedar Creek Wind LLC, 137 FERC ] 61,006, at PP 35-36
n.62 (2011) (stating that courts have recognized negotiations
regarding terms that parties to the negotiations intend to become
finalized or written contract, may in some circumstances result in
legally enforceable obligations on those parties notwithstanding the
absence of a writing). See generally Burbach Broadcasting Co. of
Delaware v. Elkins Radio Corp., 278 F.3d 401, 407-09 (4th Cir.
2002); Adjustrite Systems, Inc. v. GAB Business Serv., Inc., 145
F.3d 543, 550 (2d Cir. 1998); Miller Constr. Co. v. Stresstek, 697
P.2d 1201, 1202-04 (Idaho 1985).); see also JD Wind 1, LLC, 129 FERC
] 61,148 at P 25; Grouse Creek Wind Park, LLC, 142 FERC ] 61,187 at
PP 40-41.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
2. Reliance on RFPs and Liquid Market Hubs To Terminate Purchase
Obligation Under PURPA Section 210(m)
a. NOPR Discussion
648. In the NOPR, the Commission noted that NARUC had proposed that
the Commission allow utilities to rely on RFPs (in combination with
liquid market hubs) to establish eligibility to terminate a utility's
purchase obligation pursuant to PURPA section 210(m)(1)(C).\974\ After
describing generally how such a proposal might be structured, NARUC
suggested that ``[t]he Commission should create a yardstick of
characteristics that describe in detail how a utility could qualify for
an exemption under subparagraph (C).'' \975\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\974\ NOPR, 168 FERC ] 61,184 at P 131 (citing NARUC
Supplemental Comments, Docket No. AD16-16-000 (filed Oct. 17,
2018)).
\975\ Id., attach. A at 9.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
649. The Commission stated that, under the PURPA Regulations,
electric utilities already may seek to terminate their mandatory
purchase obligation pursuant to PURPA section 210(m)(1)(C) by
demonstrating that a particular market is of comparable competitive
quality to markets described in PURPA section 210(m)(1)(A) and
(B).\976\ The Commission further noted that the current PURPA
Regulations are not prescriptive about how an electric utility must
make such a demonstration and nothing in the PURPA Regulations or
precedent would bar an electric utility from arguing that RFPs in
combination with liquid market hubs are sufficient to satisfy PURPA
section 210(m)(1)(C).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\976\ Id. P 132 (citing Order No. 688-A, 119 FERC ] 61,305 at P
43 (``Congress believed the two types of markets identified in
subparagraphs (A) and (B), while distinct between themselves,
contain certain competitive qualities that justify termination of
the purchase requirement for any QF with nondiscriminatory access to
those markets. Subparagraph (C) directs the Commission to consider
these competitive qualities when analyzing whether there are other
markets that, while not meeting the specific requirements of
subparagraphs (A) and (B), are sufficiently competitive to justify
termination of the purchase requirement.'')); cf. Pub. Serv. Co. of
N.M., 140 FERC ] 61,191, at PP 29-38 (2012) (denying application to
terminate mandatory purchase obligation on the grounds that the Four
Corners Hub is not of comparable competitive quality to markets in
sections 210(m)(1)(A) and (B) of PURPA)).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
650. The Commission then stated that it believed that a properly
structured proposal along the lines proposed by NARUC potentially could
satisfy the statutory requirements under PURPA section 210(m)(1)(C) and
that it would consider such proposals on a case-by-case basis. Although
the Commission did not propose additional criteria a utility or
utilities may rely on to satisfy PURPA section 210(m)(1)(C), the
Commission sought comments on any specific factors that would be useful
to consider in determining how a utility or utilities may satisfy PURPA
section 210(m)(1)(C).\977\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\977\ Id. P 133.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
b. Comments
i. Comments in Opposition
651. A few commenters do not support allowing competition to be an
alternative to the mandatory purchase obligation.\978\ ELCON is
concerned that no state competitive procurement is robust enough to
replace avoided capacity costs.\979\ Solar Energy Industries supports
using RFPs to set avoided cost rates, but does not support using RFPs
to vitiate utilities' mandatory purchase obligations.\980\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\978\ Allco Comments at 17-19; Public Interest Organizations
Comments at 90.
\979\ ELCON Comments at 19.
\980\ Solar Energy Industries Comments at 24 (citing Solar
Energy Industries, Supplemental Comments, Docket No. AD16-16-000, at
10-37, 40-58 (filed Aug. 28, 2019)).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
652. Public Interest Organizations contend that RFPs are not
comparable in quality to PURPA section 210(m)(1)(A) or (B) markets
because there is only a single buyer and there are no safeguards
against the anti-competitive behavior of that buyer, such as favoring
its own or an affiliate's generation.\981\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA
state that, while they agree in principle that competition should be
the motivating force in energy markets, their experience shows that
utility-sponsored RFP programs often fall far short of genuine
competition.\982\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\981\ Public Interest Organizations Comments at 93.
\982\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 66.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
653. Public Interest Organizations state that Order No. 688-A
specifies that demonstrating that a market offers ``a meaningful
opportunity to sell'' usually requires evidence of QF transactions,
which is not possible with a market hub.\983\ Public Interest
Organizations argue that market hubs are not equivalent to PURPA
section 210(m)(1)(A) or (B) markets because, unlike an independently
administered auction, there is no guarantee that a QF will be able to
sell their energy even if it is the lowest cost resource.\984\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\983\ Public Interest Organizations Comments at 92 (citing Order
No. 688-A, 119 FERC ] 61,305 at P 38).
\984\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
654. Public Interest Organizations further contend that the
Commission does not have the authority to approve RFPs or liquid market
hubs as PURPA section 210(m)(1)(C) wholesale markets because they are
not of comparable qualify to Day 1 or Day 2 markets, i.e., to PURPA
section 210(a)(1)(A) or (B) markets.\985\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\985\ Id. at 90-91.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
ii. Comments in Support
655. Several commenters support allowing competition to be an
alternative to the mandatory purchase obligation.\986\ ELCON supports
competitive procurements that exempt industrial self-supply.\987\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\986\ Advanced Energy Economy Comments at 12; APPA Comments at
29; Colorado Independent Energy Comments at 7; Xcel Comments at 11.
\987\ ELCON Comments at 19.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
656. APPA supports the Commission reviewing factors that would
determine if a market is competitive and comparable to PURPA sections
210(m)(1)(A) and (B).\988\ Xcel proposes that the PURPA section
210(m)(1)(C) test should evaluate whether market players have a
reasonable opportunity to participate in the market, rather than
whether the type of market is similar to PURPA section 210(m)(1)(A) and
(B) markets.\989\ A few commenters requested a technical conference to
identify the criteria for determining what processes are
competitive.\990\ Colorado Independent Energy would like the RFP
standard for PURPA section 210(m)(1)(C) status to be higher than for QF
pricing and include evaluation of bid data and the modeling process to
show the absence of bias against renewable and cogeneration
[[Page 54719]]
projects and likewise the absence of bias for utility self-build
projects.\991\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\988\ APPA Comments at 26-29.
\989\ Xcel Comments at 11.
\990\ Advanced Energy Economy Comments at 13; ELCON Comments at
19.
\991\ Colorado Independent Energy Comments at 6, 11-12.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
657. Arizona Public Service agrees with NARUC that the Commission
should allow utilities to rely on RFPs to establish eligibility to
terminate the utility's purchase obligation pursuant to PURPA section
210(m)(1)(C). Arizona Public Service believes this proposal is one way
a utility could demonstrate that a market is of comparable competitive
quality to the markets described in PURPA sections 210(m)(1)(A) and
(B).\992\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\992\ Arizona Public Service Comments at 8-10.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
658. APPA argues that market hubs should be considered as possibly
comparable, particularly to PURPA section 210(m)(1)(B), which requires
that QFs have access to Commission-approved transmission service and
competitive wholesale markets for long and short-term capacity and
energy sales.\993\ APPA highlights the Commission finding that the Mid-
Columbia and Palo Verde hubs have sufficient liquidity to find just and
reasonable rates and adds that an empirical test of market liquidity
could be created.\994\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\993\ APPA Comments at 27.
\994\ Id. at 28.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
c. Commission Determination
659. In this final rule, we affirm that we will consider utility
proposals to terminate the purchase obligation pursuant to PURPA
section 210(m)(1)(C) on a case-by-case basis, including utility
proposals based on competitive solicitations or liquid market hubs.
660. In response to Public Interest Organizations, as explained
above in Section IV.A.1, PURPA section 210(m) obligates the Commission
to grant any request to terminate a utility's obligation to purchase
from a QF with nondiscriminatory access to the specified markets that
satisfy that provision. Whether any particular market is of comparable
quality to a Day 1 or Day 2 market necessarily must be determined in
the context of an individual case.
661. We refrain from outlining here an exhaustive list of factors
that will be used in any such case-by-case evaluation, but at a minimum
we will be guided by the important criteria discussed previously in
this rule in section IV.B.8 on the use of competitive solicitations to
determine avoided costs.
662. Consistent with our findings and discussion in section IV.B.4
on the use of market hubs to determine avoided cost, the Commission
finds that competitive market prices in general should reflect the
avoided cost energy rates of utilities with access to such markets in a
given region. We will therefore consider, on a case-by-case basis,
whether a properly run RFP or competitive acquisition process may also
justify termination of the PURPA purchase obligation pursuant to PURPA
section 210(m)(1)(C).
H. Legally Enforceable Obligation
1. NOPR Proposal
663. The Commission proposed to add regulatory text in 18 CFR
292.304(d)(3) to require QFs to demonstrate that a proposed project is
commercially viable and that the QF has a financial commitment to
construct the proposed project pursuant to objective, reasonable,
state-determined criteria in order to be eligible for a LEO. The
Commission further proposed to provide that states have flexibility as
to what constitutes an acceptable showing of commercial viability and
financial commitment.
664. The Commission stated that its objective in requiring a
showing of commercial viability and the QF's financial commitment to
construct the project was to ensure that no electric utility obligation
is triggered for those QF projects that are not sufficiently advanced
in their development and, therefore, for which it would be unreasonable
for a utility to include in its resource planning, while at the same
time ensuring that the purchasing utility does not unilaterally and
unreasonably decide when its obligation arises. The NOPR proposed that
states may require a showing, for example, that a QF has satisfied, or
is in the process of undertaking, at least some of the following
prerequisites: (1) Obtaining site control adequate to commence
construction of the project at the proposed location; (2) filing an
interconnection application with the appropriate entity; (3) securing
local permitting and zoning; or (4) other similar, objective,
reasonable criteria that allow a QF to demonstrate its commercial
viability and financial commitment to construct the facilities. The
NOPR stated that these proposed indicia were not intended to be
exhaustive and the Commission sought comment on these indicia and
others that also might be appropriate for consideration.
665. The Commission stated that it believed requiring QFs to
demonstrate their commercial viability and financial commitment to
construct the facilities based on such indicia before obtaining a LEO
would allow electric utilities to reliably plan their systems while
ensuring resource adequacy. Additionally, the development and
definition of objective and reasonable factors to determine commercial
viability and financial commitment to construct a facility would
encourage the development of QFs by providing QFs with more certainty
as to when they will obtain a LEO.\995\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\995\ Because QFs already in operation have necessarily
demonstrated a commitment to construct the project, the Commission
stated that it does not intend commercial viability and financial
commitment requirements to serve as prerequisites to QFs already in
operation with existing LEOs to obtaining new LEOs.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
2. Comments
a. Comments in Opposition
666. Several commenters oppose the Commission's proposal to require
QFs to demonstrate that a proposed project is commercially viable and
the QF has a financial commitment to construct the proposed project
pursuant to objective, reasonable, state-determined criteria in order
to be eligible for a LEO and that states have flexibility as to what
constitutes an acceptable showing of commercial viability and financial
commitment, arguing it undermines PURPA's intent to promote QF
development.\996\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\996\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 81; Public
Interest Organizations Comments at 98; Western Resource Councils
Comments at 144.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
667. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA argue that developers cannot
obtain financing without the financial commitment of a PPA or LEO from
the utility and therefore requiring financial viability as a condition
precedent to obtain a LEO is problematic.\997\ Western Resource
Councils argues that the NOPR proposal represents an onerous financial
and bureaucratic barrier that will lead to a substantial reduction in
the number of QFs.\998\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\997\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 81.
\998\ Western Resource Councils Comments at 144.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
668. Southeast Public Interest Organizations argue that the
proposal does not sufficiently narrow the range of divergent LEO tests
that have already been adopted by the states and opposes allowing
states additional flexibility in establishing criteria up to a fully
executed agreement.\999\ sPower requests that the Commission establish
specific criteria and prohibit states from imposing any additional
criteria.\1000\ Solar Energy Industries requests that the Commission
develop a concrete baseline
[[Page 54720]]
in determining when a QF is entitled to a purchase contract.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\999\ Southeast Public Interest Organizations Comments at 43
\1000\ sPower Comments at 14.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
669. Solar Energy Industries and Public Interest Organizations
argue that requiring developers to invest additional capital prior to
obtaining a LEO will prevent smaller companies who are unable to invest
heavily in early state development activity from participating.\1001\
Solar Energy Industries argue that it is unjust and unreasonable to
require QFs to invest millions of dollars in site control, permit
acquisition and interconnection costs in order to secure the
opportunity to negotiate with the purchasing utility. For those states
that do not willingly disclose their avoided cost rates or methodology,
the NOPR's LEO proposal requires QFs to incur substantial expense to
establish their commercial viability without a reasonable understanding
of what their rate may be.\1002\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1001\ Solar Energy Industries Comments at 41; Public Interest
Organization Comments at 80-82.
\1002\ Solar Energy Industries Comments at 41.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
670. In striking a balance between interconnection and development
risk, Solar Energy Industries proposes that the first prerequisite to a
LEO formation be either: (a) The completion of the System Impact Study
(or the equivalent in the state interconnection process); or (b) where
the utility cannot complete the System Impact Study within a reasonable
period of time, one year after tendering an interconnection request to
the host utility.\1003\ Where a QF has obtained site control, initiated
state permitting processes, submitted an interconnection request and
associated study deposit, and has been certified through the submission
of a Form No. 556, the Commission should find that the QF is eligible
to establish a LEO to sell to the purchasing utility, provided that:
(1) The QF has received a System Impact Study report (or equivalent) or
one year has elapsed since the QF's interconnection request was
tendered to the host utility; and (2) the QF commits to achieving
commercial operation within 180 days of the completion of all
interconnection facilities and network upgrades by the utility.\1004\
Solar Energy Industries asserts that QFs would, upon satisfaction of
these criteria, be legally entitled to negotiate with the purchasing
utility to develop a PPA setting forth the terms and conditions of the
purchase, including liability if the QF fails to perform. Projects that
reach agreement will proceed according to the terms of the PPA and the
purchasing utility can establish milestones with enough financial
protection to ensure that ratepayers will not be harmed if the QF fails
to begin operations.\1005\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1003\ Id. at 43.
\1004\ Id.
\1005\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
671. American Dams argues that Interconnection Agreements are
generally processed far too slowly, a problem that should be addressed
by the Commission.\1006\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1006\ American Dams Comments at 5-6.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
672. Southeast Public Interest Organizations support the
requirement of demonstrating site control, but state that requiring
permits can be time-consuming and costly such that pre-financing QFs
may not have the resources for the lengthy permitting process, and it
is unreasonable to expect a QF to incur these expenses until it has
secured a price for its output so that it can in turn secure financing
for the project.\1007\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1007\ Southeast Public Interest Organization Comments at 43-44.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
b. Comments in Support
673. Numerous commenters support the NOPR's LEO proposal, asserting
that state agencies are better positioned to develop criteria that
reflect their unique operational circumstances, resource planning needs
and risk appetite.\1008\ Several commenters note that the proposed
factors provide a reasonable balance between the planning needs of the
connecting utility and certainty to QF developers.\1009\ Several
commenters assert that requiring QFs to demonstrate commercial
viability and financial commitment will reduce the reliability or other
risks a utility faces by having to plan for its system needs or
resource adequacy around a QF that is never developed.\1010\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1008\ Alaska Power Comments at 1-2; APPA Comments at 30;
Chamber of Commerce at 8; Colorado Independent Energy Comments at
13; Connecticut Authority Comments at 24-25; Consumer Alliance
Comments at 2; Consumers Energy Comments at 5; East Kentucky
Comments at 3-4; East River at 2; El Paso Electric Comments at 6-7;
Golden Valley Comments at 7-8; Indiana Municipal Comments at 11-12;
Institute for Energy Research Comments at 2; Massachusetts DPU
Comments at 10; NARUC Comments at 7-8; NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA
Comments at 81; NRECA Comments at 21; North Carolina Commission
Staff Comments at 6; Northern Laramie Range Alliance Comments at 3-
4; Ohio Commission Energy Advocate Comments at 10; Oregon Commission
at 6.
\1009\ Alliant Energy Comments at 21; Industrial Energy
Consumers Comments at 14-16.
\1010\ Duke Energy Comments at 19; EEI Comments at 37.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
674. Several commenters agree that the proposed regulations will
provide certainty to host utilities and state commissions while
decreasing systems impact and associated costs.\1011\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1011\ Alliant Energy Comments at 21-22; NRECA at 21; Northern
Laramie Range Alliance Comments at 3-4.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
675. Connecticut Authority supports the proposal arguing that the
factors included in the NOPR will provide greater certainty and less
risk to QF developers and purchasing utilities which is consistent with
PURPA's goal of developing renewable resources.\1012\ The Chamber of
Commerce argues that the proposed factors indicate a developer's good-
faith intention to ultimately develop its proposed QF.\1013\ The
Michigan Commission states that it supports the proposal, currently has
a rulemaking and several cases pending regarding LEOs, and appreciates
any additional clarity the Commission could provide.\1014\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1012\ Connecticut Authority Comments at 24-25.
\1013\ Chamber of Commerce Comments at 8.
\1014\ Michigan Commission Comments at 7-8.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
c. Comments Requesting Modification
676. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA request that the Commission: (1)
Further define the terms ``commercial viability'' and ``financial
commitment'' to avoid litigation; (2) clarify that any changes to the
LEO rules will not affect the viability of any executed contract
between a developer and utility, regardless of the facility's
development status; and (3) clarify that the LEO rules will not
preclude nor bar any utility from executing a PPA before the QF may be
able to demonstrate compliance with the implementation of LEO
rules.\1015\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1015\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 81-83.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
i. Studies
677. NorthWestern requests that the Commission require more than
just the submission of an interconnection application prior to
obtaining a LEO in order to demonstrate that the proposal is more than
a speculative paper project.\1016\ Portland General requests that the
Commission allow states to require developers to have completed the
first interconnection study.\1017\ The South Dakota Commission states
that developers should be required to have completed a transmission
feasibility study or system impact study with a determination of the
interconnection costs the QF would be required to pay prior to
obtaining a LEO.\1018\ Portland General requests that off-system QFs be
required to have completed the first study milestone of the
transmission service request.\1019\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1016\ NorthWestern Comments at 15-16.
\1017\ Portland General Comments at 20.
\1018\ South Dakota Commission Comments at 2.
\1019\ Portland General Comments at 20.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
678. SC Solar Alliance requests that the Commission adopt a recent
South Carolina Commission ruling that a QF should be able to establish
a LEO after
[[Page 54721]]
receiving a System Impact Study or within one year if a System Impact
Study is not provided in a timely manner and that PPA in-service dates
must be extended based on interconnection delays.\1020\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1020\ SC Solar Alliance Comments at 15.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
ii. Commercial Viability
679. Alliant Energy requests that the Commission consider requiring
QF developers to have contracts in place with equipment suppliers and
an analysis of interconnections needed.\1021\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1021\ Alliant Energy Comments at 22.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
680. North Carolina Commission Staff requests that the Commission
adopt a North Carolina Commission standard that QFs must (1) commit to
sell their power via a written notice of commitment by the earlier of
105 days after submission of an interconnection request or upon receipt
of the system impact study, (2) have filed a report of proposed
construction, and (3) submitted an interconnection request under the
state's interconnection protocol which requires the QF to demonstrate
site control.\1022\ sPower argues that option contracts should be
sufficient to demonstrate site control.\1023\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1022\ North Carolina Commission Staff Comments at 6.
\1023\ sPower Comments at 15.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
iii. Financial Viability
681. Portland General and sPower suggest requiring developers to
pay a deposit to state commissions to demonstrate financial viability
with the amount based on the capacity of the QF and released upon
project completion.\1024\ Portland General asserts that having to post
a deposit encourages developers to perform sufficient due diligence
prior to claiming a LEO.\1025\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1024\ Portland General Comments at 15-16; sPower Comments at
14-15.
\1025\ Portland General Comments at 20-21.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
682. North Carolina Commission Staff argues that, in order to
protect ratepayers from QFs gaming the process, any project that backs
out of its notice of commitment should only receive as-available rates
for two years.\1026\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1026\ North Carolina Commission Staff Comments at 6.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
iv. Rejecting QF Purchases and Expanded Curtailment Rights
683. North Carolina Commission Staff suggests that the Commission
update its regulations to allow curtailing QFs when it would be
uneconomic for the utility to make such purchases.\1027\ The Institute
for Energy Research argues that the Commission should allow a utility
to reject purchases from QFs if the utility has no need for additional
capacity. The Institute for Energy Research states that such need could
be determined separately, on an annual basis, a stand-alone basis, or
as part of an IRP process.\1028\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1027\ Id. at 8.
\1028\ Institute for Energy Research Comments at 2-3.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
3. Commission Determination
684. In this final rule, we adopt the NOPR proposal to require QFs
to demonstrate that a proposed project is commercially viable and that
the QF has a financial commitment to construct the proposed project,
pursuant to objective, reasonable, state-determined criteria in order
to be eligible for a LEO.\1029\ We also affirm that the states have
flexibility as to what constitutes an acceptable showing of commercial
viability and financial commitment, albeit subject to the criteria
being objective and reasonable. We find that requiring a showing of
commercial viability and financial commitment, based on objective and
reasonable criteria, will ensure that no electric utility obligation is
triggered for those QF projects that are not sufficiently advanced in
their development, and therefore, for which it would be unreasonable
for a utility to include in its resource planning. At the same time,
the criteria ensure that the purchasing utility does not unilaterally
and unreasonably decide when its obligation arises. We believe this
strikes the right balance for QF developers and purchasing utilities
and should encourage development of QFs.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1029\ NOPR, 168 FERC ] 61,184 at P 140.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
685. Examples of factors a state could reasonably require are that
a QF demonstrate that it is in the process of at least some of the
following prerequisites: (1) Taking meaningful steps to obtain site
control adequate to commence construction of the project at the
proposed location and (2) filing an interconnection application with
the appropriate entity. The state could also require that the QF show
that it has submitted all applications, including filing fees, to
obtain all necessary local permitting and zoning approvals. We note
that the factors that the state requires must be factors that are
within the control of the QF. Thus, we clarify that it is appropriate
for states to require a QF to demonstrate that it is in the process of
obtaining site control or has applied for all local permitting and
zoning approvals, rather than requiring a QF to show that it has
obtained site control or secured local permitting and zoning.
686. We agree with Southeast Public Interest Organizations'
concerns regarding requiring QFs to obtain permits in order to
determine commercial viability. In some regions the permitting and
zoning process can be lengthy and expensive, making obtaining the
permits and zoning changes a condition to a LEO unreasonable.
Therefore, instead of requiring a QF to have secured local permitting
and zoning, states can require QFs to have applied for all of the
necessary permits and zoning variances, including the payment of all
necessary fees, as a factor in demonstrating the QF's commercial
viability. States may require a showing that such applications have
been submitted to the relevant regulatory bodies (including payment of
the application fees).
687. Several commenters argue that requiring QFs to demonstrate
financial viability prior to obtaining a LEO is problematic because QFs
need a LEO to obtain financing.\1030\ However, demonstrating the
required financial commitment does not require a demonstration of
having obtained financing. Requiring QFs to, for example, apply for all
relevant permits, take meaningful steps to seek site control, or meet
other objective and reasonable milestones in the QF's development can
sufficiently demonstrate QF developers' financial commitment in the QF
development and allows utilities to reasonably rely on the LEO in
planning for system resource adequacy. Obtaining a PPA or financing
cannot be required to show proof of financial commitment.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1030\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 81; Western
Resource Council Comments at 144.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
688. The intent of these factors is to provide a reasonable balance
between providing QFs with objective and transparent milestones up
front that are needed to obtain a LEO, allowing states the flexibility
to establish factors that address the individual circumstances of each
state, and increasing utilities' ability to accurately plan their
systems.\1031\ Establishing objective and reasonable factors is
intended to limit the number of unviable QFs obtaining LEOs and
unnecessarily burdening utilities that currently have to plan for QFs
that obtain a LEO very early in the process but ultimately are never
developed.\1032\ In adopting this provision, the Commission is raising
the bar to prevent speculative QFs from obtaining LEOs, and the
associated burden on purchasing utilities, but is
[[Page 54722]]
not establishing a barrier for financially committed developers seeking
to develop commercially viable QFs.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1031\ Alliant Energy Comments at 21; Industrial Energy
Consumers Comments at 14-16.
\1032\ Duke Energy Comments at 19; EEI Comments at 37.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
689. We disagree that establishing reasonable, transparent factors
is an onerous barrier or will cause a substantial reduction of QFs. The
objective and reasonable criteria we have established will protect QFs
against onerous requirements for a LEO that hinder financing, such as a
requirement for a utility's execution of an interconnection agreement
\1033\ or power purchase agreement,\1034\ or requiring that QFs file a
formal complaint with the state commission,\1035\ or limiting LEOs to
only those QFs capable of supplying firm power,\1036\ or requiring the
QF to be able to deliver power in 90 days.\1037\ We find that, by
making clear that such conditions are not permitted, and by providing
objective criteria to clarify when a LEO commences, the LEO provisions
we have adopted will encourage the development of QFs.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1033\ See, e.g., FLS Energy, Inc., 157 FERC ] 61,211, at P 26
(2016) (FLS) (stating that requiring signed interconnection
agreement as prerequisite to LEO is inconsistent with PURPA
Regulations).
\1034\ See, e.g., Murphy Flat Power, LLC, 141 FERC ] 61,145, at
P 24 (2012) (finding that requiring a signed and executed contract
with an electric utility as a prerequisite to a LEO is inconsistent
with PURPA Regulations.
\1035\ See, e.g., Grouse Creek Wind Park, LLC, 142 FERC ]
61,187, at P 40 (2013).
\1036\ Exelon Wind 1, L.L.C. v. Nelson, 766 F.3d 380, 400 (5th
Cir. 2014).
\1037\ Power Resource Group, Inc. v. Public Utility Com'n of
Texas, 422 F.3d 231, (5th Cir. 2005).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
690. For those commenters that requested that the Commission
establish specific factors for the states to apply, or to establish a
baseline for eligible factors, or to otherwise limit states'
flexibility, we decline to do so. Since its inception, the Commission's
PURPA Regulations have established rules and defined boundaries
allowing states flexibility within those boundaries in implementing
PURPA as appropriate for each state. As commenters noted, this allows
states to address their unique circumstances and best address each
states' needs. Furthermore, existing precedent establishes a baseline
\1038\ and this final rule's requirement that states adopt objective
and reasonable criteria for determining when a QF has obtained a LEO
provides additional safeguards (in addition to that baseline)
applicable to both QFs and utilities. Similarly, regarding Solar Energy
Industries' proposed pre-requisites and factors, for the reasons stated
above, we find that states are in the best position to determine what
specific factors would best suit the specific circumstances of that
state, so long as they are objective and reasonable, and we provide the
suggested prerequisites above as examples of objective and reasonable
factors.\1039\ While Solar Energy Industries' proposed criteria may be
reasonable, we decline to mandate specific terms for the entire
country.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1038\ For example, the Commission has held that requiring a
fully-executed contract or executed interconnection agreement as a
condition precedent to obtaining a LEO is inconsistent with PURPA.
See FLS, 157 FERC ] 61,211 at P 26; Cedar Creek Wind LLC, 137 FERC ]
61,006 at P 35.
\1039\ See supra P 685.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
691. Contrary to Solar Energy Industries' assertions, nothing in
this final rule limits a QF developer's or utility's ability to
negotiate rates, terms or conditions.\1040\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1040\ See 18 CFR 292.301(b).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
692. With regard to the argument that the NOPR's LEO proposal is
unreasonable in states that do not disclose their avoided cost rate
because it would require QFs to incur substantial expense to establish
commercial viability without a reasonable understanding of the purchase
rate, we find that such state-specific implementation issues can be
addressed case-by-case. To the extent that entities believe that a
particular state's avoided cost rates or rate setting methodologies do
not provide sufficient transparency to support a QF's ability to make
reasonable commercial viability investment decisions, such entities
could file a petition for enforcement against the state at the
Commission and, if the Commission declines to act, later file a
petition against the state in U.S. district court (pursuant to PURPA
section 210(h)(2)(B)).
693. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA request that we further define the
terms commercial viability and financial commitment. We decline. As
discussed above, we believe the best course is to allow states the
flexibility (employing objective and reasonable factors) to determine
what constitutes commercial viability and financial commitment relative
to the unique conditions or circumstances in each state but also
recognizing that existing Commission precedent establishes boundaries
of what would be considered reasonable and not discriminatory limits
for requirements in establishing a LEO.\1041\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1041\ See FLS, 157 FERC ] 61,211 at P 26; Cedar Creek Wind LLC,
137 FERC ] 61,006 at P 35.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
694. Additionally, we clarify that any changes to the LEO rules
adopted herein do not affect the viability of any executed contract or
LEO between a QF developer and utility in place as of the effective
date of this final rule, regardless of the facility's development
status. Further we clarify that nothing in the LEO rules adopted herein
precludes any utility from choosing to execute a PPA before a QF has
demonstrated compliance with the LEO rules adopted here.
Several commenters requested that the Commission require QFs to do
more than just file an interconnection application; instead, for
example, suggesting requiring completion of system impact study,
interconnection or transmission feasibility study.\1042\ We disagree.
The approach taken here recognizes the need for a QF to demonstrate
that its project is more than mere speculation, such that it is
reasonable for a utility to consider the resource in its planning
projections. A QF that has submitted an application for
interconnection, as well as having taken meaningful steps to obtain
site control and has applied for all relevant permits, while not a
guarantee that the project will be completed, are all objective and
reasonable indicators that the QF developer is seriously pursuing the
project and has spent time and resources in developing the project to
show a financial commitment. As numerous commenters have explained, QFs
need a LEO in order to obtain financing to complete the project, and we
find that, as an illustrative example, requiring the submission of an
interconnection request (as opposed to the completion of a system
impact study or transmission feasibility study) as one criteria strikes
an appropriate balance between the competing needs.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1042\ NorthWestern Comments at 15-16, Portland General Comments
at 20, South Dakota Commission Comments at 2.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
695. Moreover, it bears remembering that the concept of a LEO was
specifically adopted to prevent utilities from circumventing the
mandatory purchase requirement under PURPA by refusing to enter into
contracts.\1043\ The Commission thus has found that requiring a QF to
have a utility-executed contract or interconnection agreement, or
requiring the completion of a utility-controlled study places too much
control over the LEO in the hands of the utility and defeats the
purpose of a LEO and is inconsistent with PURPA.\1044\ When reviewing
factors to demonstrate commercial viability and financial commitment,
states thus should place emphasis on those factors that show that the
QF has taken meaningful steps to
[[Page 54723]]
develop the QF that are within the QF's control to complete, and not on
those factors that a utility controls. For example, requiring a QF to
make a deposit as Portland General and sPower proposed or whether the
QF has applied for system impact, interconnection or other needed
studies are the types of factors that may show that the QF has taken
meaningful steps to develop the QF that are within the QF's control and
the type of objective and reasonable standards that states can consider
in their implementation.\1045\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1043\ JD Wind 1, LLC, 129 FERC ] 61,148 at P 25, reh'g denied,
130 FERC ] 61,127 (citing Order No. 69 FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 30,128
at 30,880; see also Midwest Renewable Energy Projects, LLC, 116 FERC
] 61,017 (2006).
\1044\ FLS, 157 FERC ] 61,211 at P 23 (finding such requirements
``allows a utility to control whether and when a legally enforceable
obligation exists--e.g. by delaying the facilities study.'').
\1045\ Portland General Comments at 15-16; sPower Comments at
14-15.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
696. Requests by parties to expand utilities' rights to curtail QF
sales are outside the scope of this proceeding. Additionally, requests
to allow a utility to reject purchases from QFs if a utility has no
need for additional capacity are outside the scope of this proceeding.
V. Information Collection Statement
697. The Paperwork Reduction Act \1046\ requires each federal
agency to seek and obtain the Office of Management and Budget's (OMB)
approval before undertaking a collection of information (including
reporting, record keeping, and public disclosure requirements) directed
to 10 or more persons or contained in a rule of general applicability.
OMB regulations require approval of certain information collection
requirements contemplated by proposed rules (including deletion,
revision, or implementation of new requirements).\1047\ Upon approval
of a collection of information, OMB will assign an OMB control number
and an expiration date. Respondents subject to the filing requirements
of a rule will not be penalized for failing to respond to the
collection of information unless the collection of information displays
a valid OMB control number.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1046\ 44 U.S.C. 3501-21.
\1047\ See 5 CFR 1320.11.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Public Reporting Burden: The Commission is revising its regulations
implementing PURPA. At the Notice of Proposed Rulemaking (NOPR) stage,
the Commission stated the principal changes that affect information
collection involved the FERC Form No. 556.\1048\ In response to
comments arguing that the NOPR proposals would cause additional
reporting burdens, in this final rule we have analyzed whether there
are additional incremental reporting burdens that result from other
aspects of this final rule. As described further below, we find that
there is one additional potential reporting burden arising from this
final rule. It relates to reducing the PURPA section 210(m) rebuttable
presumption regarding small power production QFs' nondiscriminatory
access to certain markets from 20 MW to 5 MW. Specifically, this
reporting burden would arise from electric utilities located in markets
who choose to submit to the Commission a PURPA section 210(m) petition
for termination of the PURPA mandatory purchase obligation (affecting
information collection FERC-912) for small power production QFs between
20 MW and 5 MW.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1048\ The change to the FERC-556 described by the NOPR was
submitted under a temporary interim information collection no.,
FERC-556A (OMB Control No. 1902-0316) because another item for FERC-
556 was pending OMB review at the time and only one item per OMB
Control No. can be pending OMB review at a time. The final rule is
being submitted to OMB under FERC-556.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
698. With respect to the FERC Form No. 556, the Commission affirms
that the relevant burdens derive from the change from the Commission's
current ``one-mile rule'' for determining whether generation facilities
should be considered to be at the same site for purposes of determining
qualification as a qualifying small power production facility, to
allowing an interested person or other entity challenging a QF
certification the opportunity to file a protest, without a fee, to
rebut the presumption that affiliated small power production QFs using
the same energy resource and located more than one mile and less than
10 miles from the applicant facility are considered to be at separate
sites.
Specifically, as more fully explained in section IV.F above, and as
demonstrated by the revised Form No. 556 attached to this final rule
(but not published in the Federal Register or Code of Federal
Regulations),\1049\ the Commission makes the following changes to the
FERC Form No. 556 which affect the burden of the information
collection:
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1049\ The Form 556 and instructions will be available in the
Commission's eLibrary.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Allow an interested person or other entity challenging a
QF certification the opportunity to file a protest, without a fee, to
an initial certification (both self-certification and application for
Commission certification) filed on or after the effective date of this
final rule, or to a recertification (self-recertification or
application for Commission recertification) that makes substantive
changes to the existing certification that is filed on or after the
effective date of this final rule.
Require all applicants to report the applicant facility's
geographic coordinates, rather than only for applications where there
is no street address.
Change the current requirement to identify any affiliated
facilities with electrical generating equipment within one mile of the
applicant facility's electrical generating equipment to instead require
applicants to list only affiliated small power production QFs using the
same energy resource one mile or less from the applicant facility.
Additionally require applicants to list affiliated small
power production QFs using the same energy resource whose nearest
electrical generating equipment is greater than one mile and less than
10 miles from the electrical generating equipment of the applicant
facility.
Require the applicant to list the geographic coordinates
of the nearest ``electrical generating equipment'' of both its own
facility and the affiliated small power production QF in question based
on the definitions adopted in this final rule.
Provide space for the applicant to explain, if it chooses
to do so, why the affiliated small power production QFs using the same
energy resource, that are more than one mile and less than 10 miles
from the electrical generating equipment of the applicant facility,
should be considered to be at separate sites from the applicant's
facility, considering the relevant physical and ownership factors
identified in this final rule.
As explained in the body of this final rule, these changes in
burden are appropriate because they are necessary to meet the statutory
requirements contained in PURPA.
699. In this final rule, the Commission is revising its regulations
implementing PURPA, which will affect the information collections for
the FERC Form No. 556 and FERC-912. Below, the first table includes
estimated changes to the burden and cost of the FERC Form No. 556 due
to the final rule. As demonstrated by the table, we believe that QFs
will spend more time to identify any affiliated small power production
QFs that are less than one mile, between one and 10 miles, and more
than 10 miles, apart. The Commission expects that there will be an
increase due to the revisions to the Commission's regulations, and that
the changes to the ``one-mile rule'' and the ability to protest without
a fee will affect self-certifications and applications for Commission
certification.
[[Page 54724]]
FERC-556, Changes Due to Final Rule in Docket Nos. RM19-15-000 and AD16-16-000 \1050\
--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Increased Increased total
Annual number average burden annual burden Increased
Facility type Filing type Number of of responses Total number of hours and cost hours and total annual cost per
respondents per respondent responses per response annual cost respondent ($)
($) ($)
(1)............. (2)............. (1) * (2) = (3). (4)............ (3) * (4) = (5) (5) / (1 = (6)
--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Cogeneration and Small Power Self- no change (692). no change (1.25) no change (865). no change (1.5 no change 0
Production Facility <= 1 MW certification. hrs.); $0. (1,297.5
\1051\. hrs.); $0.
Cogeneration Facility > 1 MW. Self- no change (63).. no change (1.25) no change no change (1.5 no change 0
certification. (78.75). hrs.); $0. (118.125
hrs.); $0.
Cogeneration Facility > 1 MW. Application for no change (1)... no change (1.25) no change (1.25) no change (50 no change (62.5 0
FERC hrs.); $0. hrs.); $0.
certification.
Small Power Production Self- no change (899) no change (1.25) no change 2 hrs.; $166... 2,247.5 hrs.; 207.5
Facility > 1 MW, <= 1 Mile certification. \1052\. (1,123.75). 186,542.5.
from Affiliated Small Power
Production QF.
Small Power Production Application for no change (0)... no change (1.25) no change (0)... 6 hrs.; $498... no change (0 0
Facility > 1 MW, <= 1 Mile FERC hrs.); $0.
from Affiliated Small Power certification.
Production QF.
Small Power Production Self- no change (900). no change (1.25) no change 8 hrs.; $664... 9,000 hrs.; 830
Facility > 1 MW, > 1 Mile, < certification. (1,125). $747,000.
10 Miles from Affiliated
Small Power Production QF.
Small Power Production Application for no change (0)... no change (1.25) no change (0)... 12 hrs.; $996.. no change (0 0
Facility > 1 MW, > 1 Mile, < FERC hrs.); $0.
10 Miles from Affiliated certification.
Small Power Production QF.
Small Power Production Self- no change (899). no change (1.25) no change 2 hrs.; $166... 2,247.5 hrs.; 207.5
Facility > 1 MW, >= 10 Miles certification. (1,123.75). $186,542.5.
from Affiliated Small Power
Production QF.
Small Power Production Application for no change (0)... no change (1.25) no change (0)... 6 hrs.; $498... no change (0 0
Facility > 1 MW, >= 10 Miles FERC hrs.); $0.
from Affiliated Small Power certification.
Production QF.
--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
FERC-556, Total ................ no change ................ no change ............... 13,495 hrs.; ...............
Additional Burden and (3,454). (4,317.5). $1,120,085.
Cost Due to Final Rule.
--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
700. The table below reflects the additional estimated public
reporting burdens associated with reducing the PURPA section 210(m)
rebuttable presumption regarding small power production QFs'
nondiscriminatory access to certain markets from 20 MW to 5 MW, which
affects the FERC-912.\1053\ The FERC-912 is optional, but if electric
utilities located in relevant markets choose to submit to the
[[Page 54725]]
Commission a PURPA section 210(m) petition for termination of the PURPA
mandatory purchase obligation for small power production QFs between 20
MW and 5 MW, then we would expect the following burdens and cost
estimates to apply.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1050\ The figures in this table reflect estimated changes to
the current OMB-approved inventory for the FERC Form No. 556
(approved by the Office of Management and Budget (OMB) on November
18, 2019).
Where ``no change'' is indicated, the current figure is included
parenthetically for information only. Those parenthetical figures
are not included in the final total for column 5.
Commission staff believes that the industry is similarly
situated in terms of wages and benefits. Therefore, cost estimates
are based on FERC's 2020 average hourly wage (and benefits) of
$83.00/hour. (The submittal to and approval of OMB in 2019 for FERC
Form No. 556 was based on FERC's 2018 average annual wage hourly
rate of $79.00/hour. Because the change from the $79.00 hourly rate
to the current $83.00 hourly rate was not due to the final rule,
this chart does not depict this increase.)
\1051\ Not required to file.
\1052\ In the FERC Form No. 556 approved by OMB in 2019, for the
category ``Small Power Production Facility > 1 MW, Self-
certification,'' we estimated the number of respondents at 2,698. We
have now divided that category into three categories: ``Small Power
Production Facility > 1 MW, <= 1 Mile from Affiliated Small Power
Production QF,'' ``Small Power Production Facility > 1 MW, > 1 Mile,
< 10 Miles from Affiliated Small Power Production QF,'' ``Small
Power Production Facility > 1 MW, >= 10 Miles from Affiliated Small
Power Production QF.'' In this column, the numbers 899, 900, and 899
are a distribution of those same estimated 2,698 respondents across
the three categories.
\1053\ This information was not included in the burden estimates
in the NOPR.
FERC-912, Changes Due to Final Rule in Docket Nos. RM19-15-000 and AD16-16-000
--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Increased
Annual number Increased average hours Increased total annual annual cost
(Termination of obligation to Number of of responses Total number and cost per response burden hours and total per
purchase) respondents per respondent of responses ($) annual cost ($) respondent
(at $83/hr.)
(1) (2) (1) x (2) = (4).................... (3) * (4) = (5)........ (5)/(1) = (6)
(3)
--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Electric utility burden of reducing 30 1 30 12 hrs.; $996.......... 360 hrs.; $29,880...... $996
210(m) rebuttable presumption from
20 MW to 5 MW \1054\.
------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Total............................ 30 1 30 12 hrs.; $996.......... 360 hrs.; $29,880...... 996
--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Title: FERC-556 (Certification of Qualifying Facility (QF) Status
for a Small Power Production or Cogeneration Facility), and FERC-912
(PURPA Section 210(m) Notification Requirements Applicable to
Cogeneration and Small Power Production Facilities).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1054\ The staff estimates a total of 90 discretionary responses
may be submitted in Years 1-3, with an annual average of 30.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Action: Revisions to existing information collections FERC-556 and
FERC-912.
OMB Control No.: 1902-0075 (FERC-556) and 1902-0237 (FERC-912).
Respondents: Facilities that are self-certifying their status as a
cogenerator or small power producer or that are submitting an
application for Commission certification of their status as a
cogenerator or small power producer; electric utilities filing to
terminate their obligation to purchase, at avoided cost rates, the
output of small power production QFs between 5 MW and 20 MW.
Frequency of Information: Ongoing.
Necessity of Information: The Commission directs the changes in
this final rule revising its implementation of PURPA in order to
continue to meet PURPA's statutory requirements.
Internal Review: The Commission has reviewed the changes and has
determined that such changes are necessary. These requirements conform
to the Commission's need for efficient information collection,
communication, and management within the energy industry.
701. Interested persons may obtain information on the reporting
requirements by contacting the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission,
888 First Street NE, Washington, DC 20426 [Attention: Ellen Brown,
Office of the Executive Director], by email to [email protected]
or by phone (202) 502-8663].
Please send comments concerning the collection of information and
the associated burden estimates to: Office of Information and
Regulatory Affairs, Office of Management and Budget [Attention: Federal
Energy Regulatory Commission Desk Officer]. Due to security concerns,
comments should be sent directly to www.reginfo.gov/public/do/PRAMain.
Comments submitted to OMB should be sent within 30 days of publication
of this notice in the Federal Register and should refer to FERC-556
(OMB Control No. 1902-0075) and FERC-912 (OMB Control No. 1902-0237).
VI. Environmental Analysis
702. The Commission in the NOPR explained that it was not possible
to determine the environmental effects of the changes proposed, given
the numerous uncertainties regarding the potential effects of the
changes proposed. The Commission in the NOPR stated that, given these
uncertainties, the National Environmental Policy Act of 1969 (NEPA)
\1055\ does not require that the Commission conduct an environmental
review of the proposed revised PURPA Regulations.\1056\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1055\ 42 U.S.C. 4321 et seq.
\1056\ NOPR, 169 FERC ] 61,184 at PP 154-55.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
A. Comments
703. Several commenters argue that the Commission erred in failing
to conduct such a review.\1057\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1057\ Allco Comments at 21-22; Biological Diversity Comments at
14; NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 83; Public Interest
Organizations Comments at 21.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
704. Biological Diversity asserts an urgent need to take measures
to reduce greenhouse gas emissions to address climate change.\1058\
Biological Diversity states that the Commission's rationale for
revising the PURPA Regulations, namely the increased availability of
``fossil gas,'' requires the Commission to consider the reasonably
foreseeable impacts on climate and the environment, including on
threatened and endangered species, in order to fulfill its
responsibilities under NEPA and the Endangered Species Act (ESA).\1059\
Biological Diversity includes a list of what it alleges are reasonably
foreseeable impacts from increased use of ``fossil gas.'' \1060\
Biological Diversity maintains that the proposed revised PURPA
Regulations would prevent renewable energy development and lock in
``fossil gas'' development and supply, thereby requiring the Commission
to prepare an environmental impact statement and to obtain a biological
opinion before proceeding to a final rule.\1061\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1058\ Biological Diversity Comments at 2-7.
\1059\ Id. at 14.
\1060\ Id. at 15-17.
\1061\ Id. at 17.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
705. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA state that ``the Commission must,
at a minimum, complete the requisite scoping and other process
associated with an EA and then revise and reissue, or abandon, the NOPR
after considering the issues developed in the EA.'' \1062\ NIPPC, CREA,
REC, and OSEIA argue that it would not be too speculative for the
Commission to undertake a NEPA analysis.\1063\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and
OSEIA state that it is possible to study the environmental effects of
the NOPR proposals because the Commission undertook a NEPA analysis
when it first implemented PURPA, imposing a moratorium on certifying
cogeneration facilities as QFs until it completed an
[[Page 54726]]
Environmental Impact Statement (EIS) and recognizing the environmental
benefits from encouraging the development of QFs, and also studied the
environmental impacts for Order No. 888.\1064\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1062\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 83-85 (citing,
e.g., 42 U.S.C. 4332(A); 18 CFR 380.5, 380.4, 380.11; 40 CFR 1500.1,
1502.5; LaFlamme v. FERC, 852 F.2d 389, 397 (9th Cir. 1988); Am.
Bird Conservancy, Inc. v. FCC, 516 F.3d 1027, 1033-34 (D.C. Cir.
2008); N. Plains Res. Council, Inc. v. Surface Transp. Bd., 668 F.3d
1067, 1075 (9th Cir. 2011) (N. Plains Res. Council)).
\1063\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 92-94 (citing,
e.g., Am. Bird Conservancy, Inc. v. FCC, 516 F.3d 1033); N. Plains
Res. Council, 668 F.3d at 1076, 1078-79.
\1064\ Id. at 94-96.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
706. Public Interest Organizations state that the Commission must
prepare an Environmental Assessment (EA) in order to support its
position that this rulemaking may not have any significant foreseeable
environmental impacts.\1065\ Public Interest Organizations describe the
NOPR's ``cursory treatment of the Commission's environmental review
obligations'' as undermining NEPA's purposes ``that agencies give due
consideration to environmental impacts when making major environmental
decisions, and guaranteeing that the public is informed of such
impacts.'' \1066\ Public Interest Organizations argue that states'
exercise of new flexibility granted by the proposed revised PURPA
Regulations are reasonably foreseeable indirect and cumulative impacts
that the Commission must study. Public Interest Organizations assert
that the Commission likely will ``need to prepare a full EIS to
evaluate the serious environmental impacts that will result from
dismantling regulations that continue to play an important role in
development of renewable generation resources across the country.''
\1067\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1065\ Public Interest Organizations Comments at 21.
\1066\ Id.
\1067\ Id. at 26.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
707. NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA argue that the Commission has
failed to explain how eliminating the market for at least 10% to 20% of
renewable energy facilities would have no impact on the human
environment.\1068\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA contend that the
Commission has failed to analyze how the proposals would impact regions
like the Northwest that lack robust implementation of PURPA, the 21
states without renewable power standards (such as the Idaho, whose
Legislature affirmatively refused to adopt a renewable power standard),
or the one third of the country that is not located in an RTO or
ISO.\1069\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1068\ NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 86-87.
\1069\ Id. at 87-88.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
708. Allco argues that it is reasonably foreseeable that the
proposed revisions to the PURPA Regulations and resulting increased
fossil fuels use could add significant levels of greenhouse gas
emissions to the atmosphere and endanger the climate.\1070\ The effects
of such endangerment to the climate from fossil fuel use and reduced
renewable energy QF generation, according to Allco, include mass
extinction of species, in violation of the ESA.\1071\ Allco contends
that the Commission's failure to consult with the U.S. Fish and
Wildlife Service and the National Marine Fisheries Service
(collectively, the Services) prior to issuing the NOPR constituted a
violation of its obligations under the ESA, ``to insure that its
actions are not likely to jeopardize the continued existence of
endangered or threatened species, or result in the destruction or
adverse modification of critical habitat.'' \1072\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1070\ Allco Comments at 31.
\1071\ Id.
\1072\ Id. at 34 (quoting 16 U.S.C. 1536(a)(2)) (internal
quotations omitted).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
709. According to Allco, the PURPA NOPR triggered the ESA's
consultation requirement because the proposed changes will increase
fossil fuel generation that will, in turn, displace ``over 2 [terawatts
(TWs)] of solar generation over the next 20 years as compared to the
baseline scenario of application and faithful adherence to existing
PURPA rules.'' \1073\ Allco alleges that increased fossil-fuel
generation will ``increase land and ocean temperatures above what they
would have been, . . . resulting in increased pollution to the waters
of the United States, and harming federally endangered and threatened
species, including, without limitation, the Piping plover and the Right
whale.'' \1074\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1073\ Id.
\1074\ Id. at 34-35.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
B. Commission Determination
710. We find that no EA or EIS of the final rule is required. NEPA
requires federal agencies to prepare a detailed statement on the
environmental impact of ``major Federal actions significantly affecting
the quality of the human environment.'' \1075\ The Council on
Environmental Quality's (CEQ) regulations implementing NEPA provide
that federal agencies can comply with NEPA by preparing: (a) An
Environmental Impact Statement (EIS); or (b) an Environmental
Assessment (EA) to determine whether the proposed action significantly
affects the quality of the human environment and requires the
preparation of an EIS.\1076\ CEQ regulations also state that federal
agencies are not obligated to prepare either an EIS or an EA if they
find that a categorical exclusion applies.\1077\ Additionally, courts
have held that an EIS or EA is not required under NEPA ``unless there
is a particular project that `define[s] fairly precisely the scope and
limits of the proposed development.' '' \1078\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1075\ 42 U.S.C. 4332(C) (2018); see also Regulations
Implementing the National Environmental Policy Act, Order No. 486,
FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 30,783 (1987) (cross-referenced at 41 FERC ]
61,284).
\1076\ 40 CFR 1501.4 (2019).
\1077\ CEQ regulations state that a categorical exclusion
``means a category of actions which do not individually or
cumulatively have a significant effect on the human environment and
which have been found to have no such effect in procedures adopted
by a federal agency in implementation of these regulations and for
which, therefore, neither an environmental assessment nor an
environmental impact statement is required.'' 40 CFR 1508.4 (2019).
\1078\ Center for Biological Diversity v. Ilano, 928 F.3d 774,
780 (9th Cir. 2019) (Center for Biological Diversity) (quoting
Kleppe v. Sierra Club, 427 U.S. 390, 402 (1976)).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
711. No EA or EIS of the final rule is required because, as
discussed below, the final rule does not propose or authorize, much
less define, the scope and limits of any potential energy
infrastructure and, as a result, there is no way to determine whether
issuance of the rule will significantly affect the quality of the human
environment. In the alternative, a categorical exclusion applies so
that an EA or EIS need not be prepared. For similar reasons, there is
no requirement that the Commission engage in consultation pursuant to
the ESA with respect to this action.
1. No EIS or EA Is Required
a. There Is No Project That Defines the Scope and Limits of QF
Development
712. In Center for Biological Diversity, the court held that no
NEPA review was required with respect to actions taken by the United
States Forest Service that were similar in all relevant respects to the
action taken here by the Commission in promulgating the final rule.
That case involved the designation by the Forest Service, pursuant to
the Healthy Forests Restoration Act (HFRA), of certain forests as
``landscape-scale areas.'' Such designation meant that specific
treatments could be proposed to address insect infestation in those
designated ``landscape-scale areas.'' \1079\ The court held that no
NEPA review was required for the designations, noting that no specific
projects were proposed for any of the landscape-scale areas and stating
that ``[i]n such circumstances, `any attempt to produce an [EIS] would
be little more than a study . . . containing estimates of potential
development and attendant environmental consequences.' '' \1080\ The
court concluded that ``unless there is a particular project that
`define[s] fairly
[[Page 54727]]
precisely the scope and limits of the proposed development of the
region,' there can be `no factual predicate for the production of an
[EIS] of the type envisioned by NEPA.' '' \1081\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1079\ Center for Biological Diversity, 928 F.3d at 778.
\1080\ Id. at 780 (quoting Kleppe v. Sierra Club, 427 U.S. 390,
402 (1976)).
\1081\ Id. (quoting Kleppe, 427 U.S. at 402); see also
Northcoast Environmental Center v. Glickman, 136 F.3d 660, 668 (9th
Cir. 1998) (citing Kleppe in support of its holding that NEPA does
not require agency to complete environmental analysis where
environmental effects are speculative or hypothetical).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
713. Similarly, here, the final rule does not authorize the
development or construction of any facilities, but simply addresses the
rates that QFs can charge and certain requirements under which proposed
facilities may qualify as a QF.\1082\ The final rule does not fund any
particular QFs, or issue permits for their construction or operation
(neither of which the Commission has jurisdiction to do). The
Commission does not, in its regulations or in this final rule,
authorize or prohibit the use of any particular technology or fuel, nor
does it mandate or prohibit where QFs should be or are built. This
final rule does not exempt QFs from any Federal, state, or local
environmental, siting, or similar laws or regulatory requirements,
(again something the Commission has no authority to do).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1082\ See Sugarloaf Citizens Ass'n v. FERC, 959 F.2d 508, 514
n.29 (4th Cir. 1992) (finding that in the QF certification context
``FERC does little more than regulate the rates paid by utilities to
the qualifying facility and does not control the financing,
construction or operation of the project. Although the Facility
receives an economic benefit, no direct federal funding or other
substantial federal assistance is provided, and no licensing action
is involved.'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
714. Even with respect to rates, while the Commission has
established and here revises the factors and approaches that states can
take into account when they set QF rates, it is ultimately the states
and not the Commission that set those rates. The final rule continues
to give states wide discretion and it is impossible to know what the
states may choose to do in response to this final rule, whether they
will make changes in their current practices or not, and how those
state choices would impact QF development and the environment in any
particular state, let along any particular locale.
715. Moreover, the scope of this final rule is even less defined
than the landscape-scale area designations at issue in the Center for
Biological Diversity case. PURPA applies throughout the entire United
States, and the revisions implemented by the final rule theoretically
could affect future QF development anywhere in the country.
716. While courts have held that NEPA requires ``reasonable
forecasting,'' ``NEPA does not require a `crystal ball' inquiry.''
\1083\ Further, an agency ``is not required to engage in speculative
analysis'' or ``to do the impractical, if not enough information is
available to permit meaningful consideration'' \1084\ or to ``foresee
the unforeseeable.'' \1085\ In that vein, ``[i]n determining what
effects are `reasonably foreseeable,' an agency must engage in
`reasonable forecasting and speculation,' . . . with reasonable being
the operative word.'' \1086\ Environmental impacts are not reasonably
foreseeable if the impacts would result only through a lengthy causal
chain of highly uncertain or unknowable events.\1087\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1083\ Vt. Yankee Nuclear Power Corp. v. Nat. Res. Def. Council,
Inc., 435 U.S. 519, 534 (1978) (quoting Nat. Res. Def. Council, Inc.
v. Morton, 458 F.2d 827, 837 (D.C. Cir. 1972)).
\1084\ N. Plains Res. Council v. Surface Transp. Board, 668 F.3d
1067, 1078-79 (9th Cir. 2011) (citation omitted).
\1085\ Concerned About Trident v. Rumsfeld, 555 F.2d 817, 830
(D.C. Cir. 1976) (citation omitted).
\1086\ Sierra Club v. U.S. Dep't of Energy, 867 F.3d 189, 198
(D.C. Cir. 2017) (emphasis in original) (citation omitted).
\1087\ See Dep't of Transp. v. Pub. Citizen, 541 U.S. 752, 767
(2004) (``NEPA requires a `reasonably close causal relationship'
between the environmental effect and the alleged cause.''); Metro.
Edison Co. v. People Against Nuclear Energy, 460 U.S. 766, 774
(1983) (noting effects may not fall within section 102 of NEPA
because ``the causal chain is too attenuated'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
717. Commenters' allegations regarding potentially reduced QF
development hinge on the claim that the NOPR proposed to ``repeal'' or
``eliminate'' critical PURPA Regulations, which is not true. The
Commission proposed in the NOPR, which this final rule generally
affirms, to clarify some existing PURPA regulations and modify other
PURPA Regulations to make them consistent with the statute, based on
changed circumstances since the time those regulations originally were
promulgated. Any consideration of whether the revised rules could
potentially result in significant new environmental impacts due to less
QF development and increased development of coal, nuclear, and combined
cycle natural gas plants, would be highly speculative, based on the
difficulty in determining which additional flexibilities the final rule
provides to the states that each state will adopt, if any; how such
state rules would impact QF development going forward; and whether any
reduction in QF renewables would be replaced by the much greater amount
of non-QF renewable resources with similar environmental
characteristics.\1088\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1088\ See infra VI.B.2.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
718. As was the case in Center for Biological Diversity, any
attempt to evaluate the environmental effects of the final rule by
necessity would involve nothing less than hypothesizing the potential
development of QFs and the resultant environmental consequences.
Indeed, any attempt by the Commission to estimate the potential
environmental effects of the final rule would be considerably more
speculative than the estimates of potential development and attendant
environmental consequences that the court in Center for Biological
Diversity held are not required under NEPA. That case involved limited
zones in which some projects to treat insect infestation almost
certainly would be proposed. Here, it simply is not possible to provide
any reasonable forecast of the effects of the final rule on future QF
development, whether any affected potential QF would be a renewable
resource (such as solar or wind) or employ carbon-emitting technology
(e.g., a fossil-fuel-burning cogenerator or a waste-coal-burning small
power production facility). Moreover, environmental effects on land
use, vegetation, water quality, etc. are all dependent on location,
which are unknown and could be anywhere in the United States.
719. Because, even more so than in Center for Biological Diversity,
the final rule does not authorize, or define any limit on the scope of,
any potential QF or other infrastructure development, any attempt to
prepare an analysis of the potential effects of the final rule on
future QF development would be so speculative as to render meaningless
any environmental analysis of these impacts. Therefore, no such
analysis is required by NEPA.
b. A Categorical Exclusion Applies
720. There is a separate and independent alternative reason why no
environmental analysis is warranted: the final rule falls within a
categorical exclusion promulgated by the Commission pursuant to the
CEQ's NEPA regulations.\1089\ Specifically, the final rule falls within
the categorical exclusion for rules that: (1) Are clarifying in nature,
(2) are corrective in nature, (3) are procedural in nature, or (4) do
not substantially change the effect of the regulation being
amended.\1090\ Here, each of the revisions to the PURPA Regulations
implemented by the
[[Page 54728]]
final rule fits into one of these categories:
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1089\ CEQ regulations provide that agencies shall issue
procedures that provide specific criteria for classes of action
which ``normally do not require either an environmental impact
statement or an environmental assessment (categorical exclusion)''.
40 CFR 1507.3 (2019).
\1090\ See 18 CFR 380.4(a)(2)(ii) (categorical exclusion applies
to ``promulgation of rules that are clarifying, corrective, or
procedural, or that do not substantially change the effect of . . .
regulations being amended.'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
i. Changes That Are Clarifying in Nature
721. Several of the changes to the PURPA Regulations are clarifying
in nature. These include the changes clarifying how market prices can
be used to set as-available energy rates,\1091\ the changes clarifying
how fixed energy rates in contracts or LEOs may be determined,\1092\
and the changes clarifying how competitive solicitations can be used to
set avoided cost rates.\1093\ Other non-rate related clarifying
revisions in the final rule include a clarification regarding the
relationship between avoided costs and decreases in a purchasing
utility's load as a consequence of retail competition,\1094\ a
clarification as to how electric generating equipment should be defined
for purposes of determining whether small power production facilities
are located at the same site,\1095\ and a clarification as to when a
LEO is established.\1096\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1091\ See Sections IV.B.2-5.
\1092\ See Section IV.B.6.
\1093\ See Section IV.B.8.
\1094\ See Section IV.C.
\1095\ See Section IV.D.2.
\1096\ See Section IV.H.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
ii. Changes That Are Corrective in Nature
722. The Commission interprets the categorical exclusion for
changes to its regulations that are corrective in nature as including
changes needed in order to ensure that a regulation conforms to the
requirements of the statutory provisions being implemented by the
regulation.\1097\ To be clear, the Commission does not find that its
existing PURPA Regulations were inconsistent with the statutory
requirements of PURPA when promulgated. Rather, the Commission finds
that the changes adopted in this final rule are required to ensure
continued future compliance of the PURPA Regulations with PURPA, based
on the changed circumstances found by the Commission in this final
rule.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1097\ For example, the Commission relied on this categorical
exclusion when it revised the PURPA Regulations in 2006 to comply
with the amendments to PURPA enacted as part of EPAct 2005. See
Revised Regulations Governing Small Power Production and
Cogeneration Facilities, Order No. 671, 114 FERC ] 61,102 at P 118.
Further, this interpretation is also consistent with the Supreme
Court's holding that NEPA review is not required when an agency's
action is required by statute. See Dep't of Transp. v. Pub. Citizen,
541 U.S. 752, 770 (2004) (``where an agency has no ability to
prevent a certain effect due to its limited statutory authority over
the relevant actions, the agency cannot be considered a legally
relevant ``cause'' of the effect [and] . . . under NEPA and the
implementing CEQ regulations, the agency need not consider these
effects in its EA.''); see also Safari Club Intern. v. Jewell, 960
F.Supp.2d 17, 79-80 (D.D.C. 2013) (relying on Dep't of Transp. v.
Pub. Citizen to hold that NEPA review is not required for an agency
rule issued to comply with a statutory requirement).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
723. Three aspects of the final rule are corrective in nature. The
first is the change allowing states to require variable energy rates in
QF contracts.\1098\ As the Commission explains above, this change is
required based on the Commission's finding that, contrary to the
Commission's expectation in 1980, there have been numerous instances
where overestimates and underestimates of energy avoided costs used in
fixed energy rate contracts have not balanced out, causing the contract
rate to not violate the statutory avoided cost rate cap. Giving states
the ability to require energy rates in QF contracts to vary based on
the purchasing utility's avoided cost of energy at the time of delivery
ensures that QF rates do not exceed the avoided cost rate cap imposed
by PURPA.\1099\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1098\ See Section IV.B.7.
\1099\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
724. The second corrective aspect is the change in the PURPA
Regulations regarding the determination of what facilities are located
at the same site for purposes of complying with the statutory 80 MW
limit on small power production facilities located at the same
site.\1100\ As explained above, the Commission found, based on changed
circumstances, that the current one-mile rule is inadequate to
determine which facilities are located at the same site. Based on this
finding, the Commission was obligated by PURPA to revise its definition
of when facilities are located at the same site.\1101\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1100\ See Section IV.D.
\1101\ See Section IV.D.1.c.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
725. The third corrective aspect of the final rule relates to the
implementation of PURPA section 210(m). That statutory provision allows
purchasing utilities to terminate their obligation to purchase from QFs
that have nondiscriminatory access to certain statutorily-defined
markets, which the Commission has determined to be the RTO/ISO markets.
The final rule revises the presumption in the PURPA Regulations that
QFs with a capacity of 20 MW or less do not have non-discriminatory
access to such markets, reducing the threshold for such presumption to
5 MW.\1102\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1102\ See Section IV.G.1.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
726. The Commission has determined in the final rule that, since
the 20 MW threshold was established in 2005, the RTO/ISO markets have
matured and the industry has developed a better understanding of the
mechanics of market participation. This determination has rendered
inaccurate the presumption currently reflected in the PURPA Regulations
that QFs 20 MW and below do not have non-discriminatory access to the
relevant markets. Once the Commission made this determination, it was
appropriate for the Commission to update the 20 MW threshold to comply
with the requirements of PURPA section 210(m).\1103\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1103\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
i. Changes That Are Procedural in Nature
727. The remaining two revisions implemented by the final rule are
procedural in nature. The first is a revision to the procedures that
apply to QF certification.\1104\ The second is a revision to the
Commission's Form 556, used by QFs seeking certification.\1105\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1104\ See Section IV.E.
\1105\ See Section IV.F
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
2. The NEPA Analysis for Promulgation of the Original PURPA Regulations
in 1980 Cannot Be Replicated Here
728. As commenters note, in 1980 the Commission conducted an EA and
later an EIS for its initial rules implementing PURPA. Initially, the
Commission found (and the Final EIS also found) that new diesel
cogeneration, and dual-fuel cogeneration particularly, in New York
City, could cause significant environmental effects on air
quality.\1106\ In Order No. 70-E, however, the Commission ultimately
opted to treat such cogeneration the same as all other cogeneration
given, among other things, that the PURPA Regulations were not the
driving force behind the development of such cogeneration in New York
City.\1107\ In doing so, the Commission emphasized that QF status was
not a license nor a permit to operate but instead only entitled the QF
to a rate for purchases and to certain exemptions from regulation.
Moreover, QFs were not exempted from any Federal, state, or local
environmental, siting or other similar requirements.\1108\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1106\ Final EIS at I-7a.
\1107\ See Order No. 70-E, 46 FR 33025, 33026 (June 18, 1981).
\1108\ Id. The Commission stated in its EA that:
The rules provide encouragement to the development of certain
types of facilities. They do not prevent any facility which does not
qualify from using cogeneration or small power production, or from
using any type of fuel. The rules merely grant or deny certain
benefits to certain facilities.
In this environmental assessment, the environmental effects of
these rules are limited to the effects resulting from the
construction and/or operation of facilities which occur as a result
of the granting of these benefits, or from changes in the operating
characteristics of existing facilities which results from the
granting of these benefits. If a cogeneration or small power
production facility would be constructed or operated without the
incentives of these rules, the environmental effects resulting
therefrom cannot properly be described as environmental effects of
these rules. However, a technical and environmental discussion of
each technology is provided whether or not its use is expected to be
encouraged by these rules.
Small Power Production and Cogeneration Facilities--
Environmental Findings; No Significant Impact and Notice of Intent
To Prepare Environmental Impact Statement, 45 FR 23661, 23664 (Apr.
8, 1980) (Original PURPA EA).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
[[Page 54729]]
729. The original PURPA EA for the pre-existing PURPA Regulations
was based on a market penetration study of PURPA-induced facilities. In
order to carry out that market penetration study, the original PURPA EA
had to make the simplifying assumption that the mere implementation of
PURPA would necessarily result in the development and operation of
certain types of generation facilities that would not otherwise be
developed.\1109\ Based on these types of facilities, that EA identified
specific resource conflicts related to each type of facility, which
were nothing more than a generalized listing of potential
impacts.\1110\ That EA found that, because the various types of
facilities operate differently, there would be no cumulative impacts
and this finding, coupled with the geographic distribution of facility
development from the market penetration study, resulted in a finding of
no significant impact for all types of facilities except diesel and
dual-fueled cogeneration facilities in the Mid-Atlantic, which that EA
found could cause significant environmental impacts on air
quality.\1111\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1109\ Id. at 23,665.
\1110\ Id. at 23,675-82.
\1111\ Id. at 23,679, 23,682-83.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
730. Subsequently, an EIS was prepared that addressed only air
quality in New York City and the broader Mid-Atlantic region. The bulk
of the EIS focused on how national, state, and local air pollution
regimes would address air quality surrounding the construction and
operation of such facilities.\1112\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1112\ Order No. 70-E, 46 FR at 33026.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
731. Several commenters cite to this previous NEPA analysis
conducted in connection with the original PURPA Regulations to support
their assertion that a NEPA analysis similarly should be possible for
this rulemaking. However, those assertions are undermined by the fact
that circumstances have changed significantly since the promulgation of
the original PURPA Regulations in 1980. Prior to 1980, essentially no
QF generation technologies or other independent generation facilities
(other than those used to supply the loads of the owners rather than to
sell at wholesale) had been constructed. By contrast, today QF
generation technologies and other independent generation facilities are
common, and they are predominantly built and operated outside of
PURPA.\1113\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1113\ See supra P 240.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
732. Because there was virtually no QF or independent power
development in 1980, the original PURPA EA could reasonably project
that the incentives created by PURPA and the original PURPA Regulations
would lead to increased development of power generated by QF
technologies. The market penetration study conducted by the Commission,
and the Commission's conclusion that the PURPA Regulations could lead
to an increase in diesel-fired cogeneration in New York City, were
based on these projections.
733. By contrast, it is not possible here to make simplifying
assumptions that the mere implementation of the revised regulations
necessarily would result in specific changes in the development of
particular generation technologies compared to the status quo. First,
the revisions to the PURPA regulations are premised on a finding that,
even after the revisions, the PURPA regulations will continue to
encourage QFs. Consequently, there is no way to estimate whether any
reduction in QF development, as opposed to the status quo, will be
focused on one or more of the many different types of QF technologies,
some of which are renewable resources and some of which are fueled by
fossil fuels \1114\ and have emissions comparable to non-QF fossil
fueled generators. Moreover, because the rule primarily increases state
flexibility in setting QF rates, including giving states the option of
not changing their current rate-setting approaches, there is no way to
develop any estimate of the location or size of any hypothetical
reduction in QF development.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1114\ This would include both cogeneration, which typically is
fossil fueled, and those small power production facilities that are
fueled by waste, which would include a range of fossil fuel-based
waste. See 18 CFR 292.202(b), 292.204(b)(1).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
734. In addition, as mentioned above, renewable generation
technologies today are commonly, and even predominantly, built and
operated outside of PURPA. Current projections show that most new
generation construction will be of renewable resources.\1115\ Indeed,
the cost of renewables has declined so much that in some regions
renewables are the most cost effective new generation technology
available.\1116\ Thus, even if the final rule was to result in reduced
renewable QF development, there is little likelihood today that
hypothetical, unbuilt QFs necessarily would be replaced by new
conventional fossil fuel generation.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1115\ EIA, Annual Energy Outlook 2020, at tbl. 9 (Jan. 29,
2020) (in table see rows labeled Cumulative Planned Additions and
Cumulative Unplanned Additions in the reference case) (Annual Energy
Outlook 2020), https://www.eia.gov/outlooks/aeo/.
\1116\ See supra P 240.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
735. Alternatively, in the absence of these hypothetical, unbuilt
QFs, existing generation units--whose current emissions, if any, would
already be part of the baseline for any environmental analysis of the
impacts of the final rule--might continue to operate without any change
in their emissions; in sum, in the absence of these hypothetical,
unbuilt QFs, emissions would remain at the baseline and might not
increase at all. Indeed, in the current environment where stagnant load
growth has prevailed in recent years, this would seem to be a more
likely scenario than an alternative where these hypothetical, unbuilt
QFs are replaced by brand new fossil fuel generation that would
increase emissions over the baseline.
736. Given these facts, it would not be possible to perform a
market penetration study of the effects of the final rule that would
not be wholly speculative. Without such a study, there could be no
analysis defining the types and geographic location of facilities that
could serve as the basis for any NEPA analysis similar to that
performed in 1980.
3. This Proceeding Does Not Trigger Any ESA Consultation Requirement
737. Similar to our finding that it would be nearly impossible to
conduct a meaningful NEPA review, we disagree with Biological Diversity
and Allco that either the PURPA NOPR or this final rule trigger any
consultation requirement under the ESA.
The ESA requires that agencies consult with the Secretary of the
Interior or the Secretary of Commerce to ``insure that any action
authorized, funded, or carried out by such agency . . . is not likely
to jeopardize the continued existence of any endangered species or
threatened species or result in the destruction or adverse modification
of [critical] habitat of such species.'' \1117\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1117\ 16 U.S.C. 1536(a)(2).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
738. The ESA regulations require consultation only if the
Commission determines that a proposed action may affect listed species
or critical habitat.\1118\ We find that there are no
[[Page 54730]]
effects from the final rule for which the Commission could consult with
the Services. Under the ESA regulations, as recently revised, the
effects of an agency's action are
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1118\ 50 CFR 402.14(a).
all consequences to listed species and critical habitat that are
caused by the proposed action. A consequence is caused by the
proposed action if it would not occur but for the proposed action
and it is reasonably certain to occur.\1119\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1119\ 50 CFR 402.2 (emphasis added).
The ESA regulations also state that a consequence is not considered
to be caused by a proposed action if ``[t]he consequence is only
reached through a lengthy causal chain that involves so many steps as
to make the consequence not reasonably certain to occur.'' \1120\ This
determination must be made ``based on clear and substantial
information,'' \1121\ and ``should not be based on speculation or
conjecture.'' \1122\ In addition to the above, the same ESA regulation
states that factors for the agency to consider when determining whether
a consequence is not caused by the proposed agency action include:
``(1) The consequence is so remote in time from the action under
consultation that it is not reasonably certain to occur; or (2) [t]he
consequence is so geographically remote from the immediate area
involved in the action that it is not reasonably certain to occur[.]''
\1123\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1120\ 50 CFR 402.17(b)(3) (emphasis added).
\1121\ Id.
\1122\ Endangered and Threatened Wildlife and Plants;
Regulations for Interagency Cooperation, 84 FR 44976, 44993 (Aug.
27, 2019).
\1123\ 50 CFR 402.17(b).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
739. Because the NOPR was a proposed rule that in and of itself had
no legal effect, the NOPR is not an agency ``action'' under the
regulations implementing the ESA, which define agency action as the
``the promulgation of regulations.'' \1124\ Because the NOPR did not
constitute agency action, the Commission was not required to engage in
consultation under the ESA prior to the NOPR's issuance.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1124\ 50 CFR 402.2 (emphasis added).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
740. In this final rule, we are promulgating regulations, which
does constitute agency action. Nevertheless, for the same reasons that
an environmental review of the impacts of this final rule under NEPA
would be impossible to conduct, there is similarly no basis to conclude
that harm to endangered species is reasonably certain to occur as a
result of this final rule.
741. We find that the effects on endangered and threatened species
alleged by Allco are not reasonably certain to occur, not only because
any such harm is completely speculative, but also because it could
result only through a lengthy causal chain of highly uncertain or
unknowable events, none of which are within the Commission's authority
to authorize or preclude: (1) That the final rule causes a reduction in
the aggregate amount of QF capacity constructed in the future; (2) that
any reduction in renewable resource QFs would not be offset by
increased construction of renewable resources outside of PURPA,
resulting from either other incentive programs or simply the increased
cost-competitiveness of such resources; (3) that construction of such
non-QF renewable resources would yield an increase in carbon emissions
resulting from the reduction in renewable resource QFs that is not
offset by other renewable resources; and (4) that such increase in
carbon emissions would have an adverse effect on endangered and
threatened species. Furthermore, the consequences of this rule would be
remote in time and geographically remote because it would require
action by individual generators, QF or non-QF, to propose, site,
permit, construct, and operate a facility, in underdetermined locations
potentially anywhere in the United States. In addition, many of these
generators, QF and non-QF, would be subject to state approval and
permitting requirements over which the Commission has no control.
742. Further, there is no support in the record for Allco's claim
that the changes proposed in the PURPA NOPR would displace over 2 TWs
of solar generation over the next 20 years.\1125\ Allco provides no
citation or other support whatsoever for this assertion but simply
makes the claim with no elaboration. We find that such speculation or
conjecture provides no basis upon which to either initiate or conduct
any meaningful consultation with the Services on the impacts to
endangered species from this final rule.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1125\ Allco Comments at 34.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
VII. Regulatory Flexibility Act Certification
743. The Regulatory Flexibility Act of 1980 (RFA) \1126\ generally
requires a description and analysis of rules that will have significant
economic impact on a substantial number of small entities. In lieu of
preparing a regulatory flexibility analysis, an agency may certify that
a rule will not have a significant economic impact on a substantial
number of small entities.\1127\ The Commission in the NOPR stated that
the proposed rule would not significantly impact a substantial number
of small entities. Some commenters argue otherwise.\1128\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1126\ 5 U.S.C. 601-12.
\1127\ 5 U.S.C. 605(b).
\1128\ See Allco Comments at 33.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
744. The Small Business Administration's (SBA) Office of Size
Standards develops the numerical definition of a small business.\1129\
The SBA size standard for electric utilities is based on the number of
employees, including affiliates.\1130\ Under SBA's current size
standards, the threshold for a small entity (including its affiliates)
is 250 employees for cogeneration and small power production applicants
in the following NAICS \1131\ categories:
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1129\ 13 CFR 121.101.
\1130\ SBA final rule on ``Small Business Size Standards:
Utilities,'' 78 FR 77343 (Dec. 23, 2013).
\1131\ The North American Industry Classification System (NAICS)
is an industry classification system that Federal statistical
agencies use to categorize businesses for the purpose of collecting,
analyzing, and publishing statistical data related to the U.S.
economy. United States Census Bureau, North American Industry
Classification System, https://www.census.gov/eos/www/naics/
(accessed April 11, 2018).
NAICS code 221114 for Solar Electric Power Generation
NAICS code 221115 for Wind Electric Power Generation
NAICS code 221116 for Geothermal Electric Power Generation
NAICS code 221117 for Biomass Electric Power Generation
NAICS code 221118 for Other Electric Power Generation
The threshold for a small entity (including its affiliates) is 500
employees for NAICS code 221111 for Hydroelectric Power Generation.
745. This rule directly affects qualifying small power production
facilities and cogeneration facilities, the majority of which the
Commission estimates are small businesses. With respect to the changes
related to the Form No. 556 and new protests allowed pursuant to this
rule, as reflected in the burden and cost estimates provided above, the
Commission does not anticipate that any additional reporting burden or
cost imposed on QFs, regardless of their status as a small or large
business, would be significant. Those revisions may result in
additional information being submitted by some small power production
QF applicants (especially those with affiliated small power production
qualifying facilities using the same energy resource located over one
and less than 10 miles away). The Commission estimates that less than
10 percent of QF applications and self-certifications meet these
criteria.
[[Page 54731]]
746. In the final analysis, the other changes in this final rule
\1132\ largely impact payments to QFs by electric utilities. More
accurate avoided cost rates may result in lower payments from certain
electric utilities to certain QFs. In this regard, the final rule
provides states greater flexibility than they have today to set the
rate that electric utilities will pay QFs, but there is no way to know
in advance which new flexibility state regulatory authorities and
nonregulated electric utilities will exercise, or what impact that new
flexibility might have given the different circumstances likely to
apply to each determination of avoided cost. Under the final rule,
additionally, states also have the discretion to continue setting the
rate as they do today and not to adopt the Commission' proposed greater
rate flexibilities. Therefore, it is not possible to estimate what the
dollar impact might be. However, because of the way PURPA is
structured, whatever the potential dollar impacts of these changes on
small QFs may be, to the extent that they reduce the amounts paid to
certain QFs, such reductions could be matched dollar-for-dollar by
savings experienced by purchasing electric utilities, which should be
flowed through to their retail ratepayers, some of whom would also tend
to qualify as small entities.\1133\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1132\ I.e., use of locational marginal prices, competitive
market price, and use of forecasted stream of market revenues for
energy rate component of QF contracts or legally enforceable
obligations; use of variable energy rates in QF contracts or legally
enforceable obligations; use of competitive solicitations to set
avoided energy and capacity rates; reducing the PURPA section 210(m)
rebuttable presumption regarding access to markets from 20 MW to 5
MW; and the commercial viability and financial commitment to
construct demonstration necessary to obtaining a legally enforceable
obligation.
\1133\ While this potential beneficial impact on retail
ratepayers would be an indirect impact of this final rule, the Small
Business Administration Office of Advocacy encourages such indirect
costs to be analyzed as well: ``Although it is not required by the
RFA, the Office of Advocacy believes that it is good public policy
for the agency to perform a regulatory flexibility analysis even
when the impacts of its regulation are indirect.'' SBA, Office of
Advocacy, A Guide for Government Agencies: How to Comply with the
Regulatory Flexibility Act at 23 (Aug. 2017), https://www.sba.gov/sites/default/files/advocacy/How-to-Comply-with-the-RFA-WEB.pdf. But
see Mid-Tex Elec. Co-op., Inc. v. FERC, 773 F.2d 327, 343 (D.C. Cir.
1985) (``Congress did not intend to require that every agency
consider every indirect effect that any regulation might have on
small businesses in any stratum of the national economy.'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
747. While Allco argues that the Commission should have attempted
to minimize the impacts on small renewable energy producers and
consider alternative structures, the fact is that these offsetting
impacts result from changes that are necessary to ensure the
Commission's regulations continue to meet PURPA's statutory
requirements. For example, allowing states to use competitive prices
may benefit small QFs inasmuch as the rate-setting process for
purchases of energy from these entities would be more straightforward
and efficient than the administrative processes currently in use.
Furthermore, providing flexibility in setting energy rates may result
in state entities approving longer duration contracts for capacity (at
fixed rates) and energy. The impacts of these changes, therefore, are
reasonable alternatives to the status quo while adhering to the
requirements of PURPA.
748. This final rule establishes a rebuttable presumption that a
qualifying small power production facility whose electrical generating
equipment is more than one but less than 10 miles from affiliated
electrical generating equipment using the same energy resource is at a
separate site. The Commission finds that this rebuttable presumption
imposes a lower burden than imposing a rule that any affiliated
electrical generating equipment less than 10 miles apart is presumed to
be at the same site. Similarly, the Commission, while removing the
rebuttable presumption that qualifying small power production
facilities more than 5 MW but under 20 MW lack nondiscriminatory
access, has provided factors that such facilities could use to
demonstrate lack of such access--allowing them to retain the mandatory
purchase obligation. The Commission estimates that annual additional
compliance costs on industry (detailed above) will be approximately
$1,149,965 (or an average additional burden and cost per response, of
3.187 hrs. and the corresponding $264.51) to comply with these
requirements.\1134\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1134\ Annual additional cost of $1,149,965 [($1,120,085 for
FERC-556) + (29,880 for FERC-912)] and average additional burden of
13,855 hours [(13,495 hrs. for FERC-556) + (360 hrs. for FERC-912)]
divided by the number of affected responses of 4,347.5 [(4,317.5 for
FERC-556) + (30 responses for FERC-912)].
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
749. Accordingly, pursuant to section 605(b) of the RFA, the
Commission certifies that this rule will not have a significant
economic impact on a substantial number of small entities.
VIII. Document Availability
750. In addition to publishing the full text of this document in
the Federal Register, the Commission provides all interested persons an
opportunity to view and/or print the contents of this document via the
internet through the Commission's Home Page (https://www.ferc.gov). At
this time, the Commission has suspended access to the Commission's
Public Reference Room due to the President's March 13, 2020
proclamation declaring a National Emergency concerning the Novel
Coronavirus Disease (COVID-19).
751. From the Commission's Home Page on the internet, this
information is available on eLibrary. The full text of this document is
available on eLibrary in PDF and Microsoft Word format for viewing,
printing, and/or downloading. To access this document in eLibrary, type
the docket number excluding the last three digits of this document in
the docket number field.
752. User assistance is available for eLibrary and the Commission's
website during normal business hours from the Commission's Online
Support at 202-502-6652 (toll free at 1-866-208-3676) or email at
[email protected], or the Public Reference Room at (202) 502-
8371, TTY (202)502-8659. Email the Public Reference Room at
[email protected].
IX. Effective Dates and Congressional Notification
753. These regulations are effective December 31, 2020. The
Commission has determined, with the concurrence of the Administrator of
the Office of Information and Regulatory Affairs of OMB, that this rule
is not a ``major rule'' as defined in section 351 of the Small Business
Regulatory Enforcement Fairness Act of 1996. This final rule is being
submitted to the Senate, House, Government Accountability Office, and
Small Business Administration.
List of Subjects in 18 CFR Part 292
Electric power plants; Electric utilities, Reporting and
recordkeeping requirements.
List of Subjects in 18 CFR Part 375
Authority delegations (Government agencies); Seals and insignia;
Sunshine Act.
By the Commission. Commissioner Glick is dissenting in part with a
separate statement attached.
Issued: July 16, 2020.
Nathaniel J. Davis, Sr.,
Deputy Secretary.
In consideration of the foregoing, the Commission amends parts 292
and 375, chapter I, title 18, Code of Federal Regulations, as follows.
SUBCHAPTER K--REGULATIONS UNDER THE PUBLIC UTILITY REGULATORY
POLICIES ACT OF 1978
* * * * *
[[Page 54732]]
PART 292--REGULATIONS UNDER SECTIONS 201 AND 210 OF THE PUBLIC
UTILITY REGULATORY POLICIES ACT OF 1978 WITH REGARD TO SMALL POWER
PRODUCTION AND COGENERATION
0
1. The authority citation for part 292 continues to read as follows:
Authority: 16 U.S.C. 791a-825r, 2601-2645; 31 U.S.C. 9701; 42
U.S.C. 7101-7352.
0
2. Amend Sec. 292.101 by adding paragraphs (b)(12) through (16) to
read as follows:
Sec. 292.101 Definitions.
* * * * *
(12) Locational marginal price means the price for energy at a
particular location as determined in a market defined in Sec.
292.309(e), (f), or (g).
(13) Competitive Price means a Market Hub Price or a Combined Cycle
Price.
(14) Market Hub Price means a price for as-delivered energy
determined pursuant to Sec. 292.304(b)(7)(i).
(15) Combined Cycle Price means a price for as-delivered energy
determined pursuant to Sec. 292.304(b)(7)(ii).
(16) Competitive Solicitation Price means a price for energy and/or
capacity determined pursuant to Sec. 292.304(b)(8).
0
3. Amend Sec. 292.202 by adding paragraph (t) to read as follows:
Sec. 292.202 Definitions.
* * * * *
(t) Electrical generating equipment means all boilers, heat
recovery steam generators, prime movers (any mechanical equipment
driving an electric generator), electrical generators, photovoltaic
solar panels, inverters, fuel cell equipment and/or other primary power
generation equipment used in the facility, excluding equipment for
gathering energy to be used in the facility.
0
4. Amend Sec. 292.204 by revising paragraph (a) to read as follows:
Sec. 292.204 Criteria for qualifying small power production
facilities.
(a) Size of the facility--(1) Maximum size. Except as provided in
paragraph (a)(4) of this section, the power production capacity of a
facility for which qualification is sought, together with the power
production capacity of any other small power production qualifying
facilities that use the same energy resource, are owned by the same
person(s) or its affiliates, and are located at the same site, may not
exceed 80 megawatts.
(2) Method of calculation. (i)(A) For purposes of this paragraph
(a)(2), there is an irrebuttable presumption that affiliated small
power production qualifying facilities that use the same energy
resource and are located one mile or less from the facility for which
qualification or recertification is sought are located at the same site
as the facility for which qualification or recertification is sought.
(B) For purposes of this paragraph (a)(2), for facilities for which
qualification or recertification is filed on or after December 31, 2020
there is an irrebuttable presumption that affiliated small power
production qualifying facilities that use the same energy resource and
are located 10 miles or more from the facility for which qualification
or recertification is sought are located at separate sites from the
facility for which qualification or recertification is sought.
(C) For purposes of this paragraph (a)(2), for facilities for which
qualification or recertification is filed on or after December 31,
2020, there is a rebuttable presumption that affiliated small power
production qualifying facilities that use the same energy resource and
are located more than one mile and less than 10 miles from the facility
for which qualification or recertification is sought are located at
separate sites from the facility for which qualification or
recertification is sought.
(D) For hydroelectric facilities, facilities are considered to be
located at the same site as the facility for which qualification or
recertification is sought if they are located within one mile of the
facility for which qualification or recertification is sought and use
water from the same impoundment for power generation.
(ii) For purposes of making the determinations in paragraph
(a)(2)(i), the distance between two facilities shall be measured from
the edge of the closest electrical generating equipment for which
qualification or recertification is sought to the edge of the nearest
electrical generating equipment of the other affiliated small power
production qualifying facility using the same energy resource.
(3) Waiver. The Commission may modify the application of paragraph
(a)(2) of this section, for good cause.
(4) Exception. Facilities meeting the criteria in section 3(17)(E)
of the Federal Power Act (16 U.S.C. 796(17)(E)) have no maximum size,
and the power production capacity of such facilities shall be excluded
from consideration when determining the size of other small power
production facilities less than 10 miles from such facilities.
* * * * *
0
5. Amend Sec. 292.207 by:
0
a. Revising paragraphs (a), (b) intructory text, (b)(2), (c), and (d);
0
b. Adding paragraphs (e) and (f).
The revisions and additions read as follows:
Sec. 292.207 Procedures for obtaining qualifying status.
(a) Self-certification. (1) FERC Form No. 556. The qualifying
facility status of an existing or a proposed facility that meets the
requirements of Sec. 292.203 may be self-certified by the owner or
operator of the facility or its representative by properly completing a
FERC Form No. 556 and filing that form with the Commission, pursuant to
Sec. 131.80 of this chapter, and complying with paragraph (e) of this
section.
(2) Factors. For small power production facilities pursuant to
Sec. 292.204, the owner or operator of the facility or its
representative may, when completing the FERC Form No. 556, provide
information asserting factors showing that the facility for which
qualification or recertification is sought is at a separate site from
other facilities using the same energy resource and owned by the same
person(s) or its affiliates.
(3) Commission action. Self-certification and self-recertification
are effective upon filing. If no protests to a self-certification or
self-recertification are timely filed pursuant to paragraph (c) of this
section, no further action by the Commission is required for a self-
certification or self-recertification to be effective. If protests to a
self-certification or self-recertification are timely filed pursuant to
paragraph (c) of this section, a self-certification or self-
recertification will remain effective until the Commission issues an
order revoking QF certification. The Commission will act on the protest
within 90 days from the date the protest is filed; provided that, if
the Commission requests more information from the protester, the entity
seeking qualification or recertification, or both, the time for the
Commission to act will be extended to 60 days from the filing of a
complete answer to the information request. In addition to any
extension resulting from a request for information, the Commission also
may toll the 90-day period for one additional 60-day period if so
required to rule on a protest. Authority to toll the 90-day period for
this purpose is delegated to the Secretary or the Secretary's designee.
Absent Commission action before the expiration of the tolling period, a
protest will be deemed denied, and the self-certification or self-
recertification will remain effective.
[[Page 54733]]
(b) Optional procedure--Commission certification. * * *
(2) General contents of application. The application must include a
properly completed FERC Form No. 556 pursuant to Sec. 131.80 of this
chapter. For small power production facilities pursuant to Sec.
292.204, the owner or operator of the facility or its representative
may, when completing the FERC Form No. 556, provide information
asserting factors showing that the facility for which qualification is
sought is at a separate site from other facilities using the same
energy resource and owned by the same person(s) or its affiliates.
* * * * *
(c) Protests and Interventions. (1) Filing a Protest. Any person,
as defined in Sec. 385.102(d) of this chapter, who opposes either a
self-certification or self-recertification making substantive changes
to the existing certification filed pursuant to paragraph (a) of this
section or an application for Commission certification or Commission
recertification making substantive changes to the existing
certification filed pursuant to paragraph (b) of this section for which
qualification or recertification is filed on or after December 31,
2020, may file a protest with the Commission. Any protest to and any
intervention in a self-certification or self-recertification must be
filed in accordance with Sec. Sec. 385.211 and 385.214 of this
chapter, on or before 30 days from the date the self-certification or
self-recertification is filed. Any protestor must concurrently serve a
copy of such filing pursuant to Sec. 385.211 of this chapter. Any
protest must be adequately supported, and provide any supporting
documents, contracts, or affidavits to substantiate the claims in the
protest.
(2) Limitations on protest. Protests may be filed to any initial
self-certification or application for Commission certification filed on
or after the effective date of this final rule, and to any self-
recertification or application for Commission recertification that are
filed on or after December 31, 2020 that makes substantive changes to
the existing certification. Once the Commission has certified an
applicant's qualifying facility status either in response to a protest
opposing a self-certification or self-recertification, or in response
to an application for Commission certification or Commission
recertification, any later protest to a self-recertification or
application for Commission recertification making substantive changes
to a qualifying facility's certification must demonstrate changed
circumstances that call into question the continued validity of the
certification.
(d) Response to protests. Any response to a protest must be filed
on or before 30 days from the date of filing of that protest and will
be allowed under Sec. 385.213(a)(2) of this chapter.
(e) Notice requirements. (1) General. An applicant filing a self-
certification, self-recertification, application for Commission
certification or application for Commission recertification of the
qualifying status of its facility must concurrently serve a copy of
such filing on each electric utility with which it expects to
interconnect, transmit or sell electric energy to, or purchase
supplementary, standby, back-up or maintenance power from, and the
State regulatory authority of each state where the facility and each
affected electric utility is located. The Commission will publish a
notice in the Federal Register for each application for Commission
certification and for each self-certification of a cogeneration
facility that is subject to the requirements of Sec. 292.205(d).
(2) Facilities of 500 kW or more. An electric utility is not
required to purchase electric energy from a facility with a net power
production capacity of 500 kW or more until 90 days after the facility
notifies the facility that it is a qualifying facility or 90 days after
the utility meets the notice requirements in paragraph (c)(1) of this
section.
(f) Revocation of qualifying status. (1)(i) If a qualifying
facility fails to conform with any material facts or representations
presented by the cogenerator or small power producer in its submittals
to the Commission, the notice of self-certification or Commission order
certifying the qualifying status of the facility may no longer be
relied upon. At that point, if the facility continues to conform to the
Commission's qualifying criteria under this part, the cogenerator or
small power producer may file either a notice of self-recertification
of qualifying status pursuant to the requirements of paragraph (a) of
this section, or an application for Commission recertification pursuant
to the requirements of paragraph (b) of this section, as appropriate.
(ii) The Commission may, on its own motion or on the motion of any
person, revoke the qualifying status of a facility that has been
certified under paragraph (b) of this section, if the facility fails to
conform to any of the Commission's qualifying facility criteria under
this part.
(iii) The Commission may, on its own motion or on the motion of any
person, revoke the qualifying status of a self-certified or self-
recertified qualifying facility if it finds that the self-certified or
self-recertified qualifying facility does not meet the applicable
requirements for qualifying facilities.
(2) Prior to undertaking any substantial alteration or modification
of a qualifying facility which has been certified under paragraph (b)
of this section, a small power producer or cogenerator may apply to the
Commission for a determination that the proposed alteration or
modification will not result in a revocation of qualifying status. This
application for Commission recertification of qualifying status should
be submitted in accordance with paragraph (b) of this section.
0
6. Amend Sec. 292.304 by:
0
a. Adding paragraph (b)(6) through (8); and
0
b. Revising paragraphs (d) and (e).
The additions and revisions read as follows:
Sec. 292.304 Rates for purchases.
* * * * *
(b) Relationship to avoided costs.
* * *
(6) Locational Marginal Price. There is a rebuttable presumption
that a state regulatory authority or nonregulated electric utility may
use a Locational Marginal Price as a rate for as-available qualifying
facility energy sales to electric utilities located in a market defined
in Sec. 292.309(e), (f), or (g).
(7) Competitive Price. A state regulatory authority or nonregulated
electric utility may use a Competitive Price as a rate for as-available
qualifying facility energy sales to electric utilities located outside
a market defined in Sec. 292.309(e), (f), or (g). A Competitive Price
may be either a Market Hub Price or a Combined Cycle Price, determined
as follows:
(i) A Market Hub Price is a price established at a liquid market
hub which a state regulatory authority or nonregulated electric utility
determines represents an appropriate measure of the electric utility's
avoided cost for as-available energy, and is a hub to which the
electric utility has reasonable access, based on an evaluation by the
state regulatory authority or nonregulated electric utility of the
relevant factors, including but not limited to the following:
(A) Whether the hub is sufficiently liquid that prices at the hub
represent a competitive price;
(B) Whether prices developed at the hub are sufficiently
transparent;
(C) Whether the electric utility has the ability to deliver power
from such hub to its load, even if its load is not directly connected
to the hub; and
[[Page 54734]]
(D) Whether the hub represents an appropriate market to derive an
energy price for the electric utility's purchases from the relevant
qualifying facility given the electric utility's physical proximity to
the hub or other factors.
(ii) A Combined Cycle Price is a price determined pursuant to a
formula established by a state regulatory authority or nonregulated
electric utility using published natural gas price indices, a proxy
heat rate, and variable operations and maintenance costs for an
efficient natural gas combined-cycle generating facility. Before
establishing such a formula rate, a state regulatory authority or
nonregulated electric utility must determine that the resulting
Combined Cycle Price represents an appropriate measure of the
purchasing electric utility's avoided cost for energy, based on its
evaluation of the relevant factors, including but not limited to the
following:
(A) Whether the cost of energy from an efficient natural gas
combined cycle generating facility represents a reasonable measure of a
competitive price in the purchasing electric utility's region;
(B) Whether natural gas priced pursuant to particular proposed
natural gas price indices would be available in the relevant market;
(C) Whether there should be an adjustment to the natural gas price
to appropriately reflect the cost of transporting natural gas to the
relevant market; and
(D) Whether the proxy heat rate used in the formula should be
updated regularly to reflect improvements in generation technology.
(8) Competitive Solicitation Price. (i) A state regulatory
authority or nonregulated electric utility may use a price determined
pursuant to a competitive solicitation process to establish qualifying
facility energy and/or capacity rates for sales to electric utilities,
provided that such competitive solicitation process is conducted
pursuant to procedures ensuring the solicitation is conducted in a
transparent and non-discriminatory manner including, but not limited
to, the following:
(A) The solicitation process is an open and transparent process
that includes, but is not limited to, providing equally to all
potential bidders substantial and meaningful information regarding
transmission constraints, levels of congestion, and interconnections,
subject to appropriate confidentiality safeguards;
(B) Solicitations are open to all sources, to satisfy that electric
utility's capacity needs, taking into account the required operating
characteristics of the needed capacity;
(C) Solicitations are conducted at regular intervals;
(D) Solicitations are subject to oversight by an independent
administrator; and
(E) Solicitations are certified as fulfilling the above criteria by
the relevant state regulatory authority or nonregulated electric
utility through a post-solicitation report.
(ii) To the extent that the electric utility procures all of its
capacity, including capacity resources constructed or otherwise
acquired by the electric utility, through a competitive solicitation
process conducted pursuant to paragraph (b)(8)(i) of this section, the
electric utility shall be presumed to have no avoided capacity costs
unless and until it determines to acquire capacity outside of such
competitive solicitation process. However, the electric utility shall
nevertheless be required to purchase energy from qualifying small power
producers and qualifying cogeneration facilities.
(iii) To the extent that the electric utility does not procure all
of its capacity through a competitive solicitation process conducted
pursuant to paragraph (b)(8)(i) of this section, then there shall be no
presumption that the electric utility has no avoided capacity costs.
* * * * *
(d) Purchases ``as available'' or pursuant to a legally enforceable
obligation. (1) Each qualifying facility shall have the option either:
(i) To provide energy as the qualifying facility determines such
energy to be available for such purchases, in which case the rates for
such purchases shall be based on the electric utility's avoided cost
for energy calculated at the time of delivery; or
(ii) To provide energy or capacity pursuant to a legally
enforceable obligation for the delivery of energy or capacity over a
specified term, in which case the rates for such purchases shall,
except as provided in paragraph (d)(2) of this section, be based on
either:
(A) The avoided costs calculated at the time of delivery; or
(B) The avoided costs calculated at the time the obligation is
incurred.
(iii) The rate for delivery of energy calculated at the time the
obligation is incurred may be based on estimates of the present value
of the stream of revenue flows of future locational marginal prices, or
Competitive Prices during the anticipated period of delivery.
(2) Notwithstanding paragraph (d)(1)(ii)(B) of this section, a
state regulatory authority or nonregulated electric utility may require
that rates for purchases of energy from a qualifying facility pursuant
to a legally enforceable obligation vary through the life of the
obligation, and be set at the electric utility's avoided cost for
energy calculated at the time of delivery.
(3) Obtaining a legally enforceable obligation. A qualifying
facility must demonstrate commercial viability and financial commitment
to construct its facility pursuant to criteria determined by the state
regulatory authority or nonregulated electric utility as a prerequisite
to a qualifying facility obtaining a legally enforceable obligation.
Such criteria must be objective and reasonable.
(e) Factors affecting rates for purchases. (1) A state regulatory
authority or nonregulated electric utility may establish rates for
purchases of energy from a qualifying facility based on a purchasing
electric utility's locational marginal price calculated by the
applicable market defined in Sec. 292.309(e), (f), or (g), or the
purchasing electric utility's applicable Competitive Price.
Alternatively, a state regulatory authority or nonregulated electric
utility may establish rates for purchases of energy and/or capacity
from a qualifying facility based on a Competitive Solicitation Price.
To the extent that capacity rates are not set pursuant to this section,
capacity rates shall be set pursuant to subsection (2).
(2) To the extent that a state regulatory authority or nonregulated
electric utility does not set energy and/or capacity rates pursuant to
paragraph (e)(1) of this section, the following factors shall, to the
extent practicable, be taken into account in determining rates for
purchases from a qualifying facility:
(i) The data provided pursuant to Sec. 292.302(b), (c), or (d),
including State review of any such data;
(ii) The availability of capacity or energy from a qualifying
facility during the system daily and seasonal peak periods, including:
(A) The ability of the electric utility to dispatch the qualifying
facility;
(B) The expected or demonstrated reliability of the qualifying
facility;
(C) The terms of any contract or other legally enforceable
obligation, including the duration of the obligation, termination
notice requirement and sanctions for non-compliance;
(D) The extent to which scheduled outages of the qualifying
facility can be usefully coordinated with scheduled outages of the
electric utility's facilities;
[[Page 54735]]
(E) The usefulness of energy and capacity supplied from a
qualifying facility during system emergencies, including its ability to
separate its load from its generation;
(F) The individual and aggregate value of energy and capacity from
qualifying facilities on the electric utility's system; and
(G) The smaller capacity increments and the shorter lead times
available with additions of capacity from qualifying facilities; and
(iii) The relationship of the availability of energy or capacity
from the qualifying facility as derived in paragraph (e)(2)(ii) of this
section, to the ability of the electric utility to avoid costs,
including the deferral of capacity additions and the reduction of
fossil fuel use; and
(iv) The costs or savings resulting from variations in line losses
from those that would have existed in the absence of purchases from a
qualifying facility, if the purchasing electric utility generated an
equivalent amount of energy itself or purchased an equivalent amount of
electric energy or capacity.
* * * * *
0
7. Amend Sec. 292.309 by revising paragraphs (c), (d), (e), and (f) to
read as follows:
Sec. 292.309 Termination of obligation to purchase from qualifying
facilities.
* * * * *
(c) For purposes of paragraphs (a)(1), (2) and (3) of this section,
with the exception of paragraph (d) of this section, there is a
rebuttable presumption that a qualifying facility has nondiscriminatory
access to the market if it is eligible for service under a Commission-
approved open access transmission tariff or Commission-filed
reciprocity tariff, and Commission-approved interconnection rules.
(1) If the Commission determines that a market meets the criteria
of paragraphs (a)(1), (2) or (3) of this section, and if a qualifying
facility in the relevant market is eligible for service under a
Commission-approved open access transmission tariff or Commission-filed
reciprocity tariff, a qualifying facility may seek to rebut the
presumption of access to the market by demonstrating, inter alia, that
it does not have access to the market because of operational
characteristics or transmission constraints.
(2) For purposes of paragraphs (a)(1), (2), and (3) of this
section, a qualifying small power production facility with a capacity
between 5 megawatts and 20 megawatts may additionally seek to rebut the
presumption of access to the market by demonstrating that it does not
have access to the market in light of consideration of other factors,
including, but not limited to:
(i) Specific barriers to connecting to the interstate transmission
grid, such as excessively high costs and pancaked delivery rates;
(ii) Unique circumstances impacting the time or length of
interconnection studies or queues to process the small power production
facility's interconnection request;
(iii) A lack of affiliation with entities that participate in the
markets in paragraphs (a)(1), (2), and (3) of this section;
(iv) The qualifying small power production facility has a
predominant purpose other than selling electricity and should be
treated similarly to qualifying cogeneration facilities;
(v) The qualifying small power production facility has certain
operational characteristics that effectively prevent the qualifying
facility's participation in a market; or
(vi) The qualifying small power production facility lacks access to
markets due to transmission constraints. The qualifying small power
production facility may show that it is located in an area where
persistent transmission constraints in effect cause the qualifying
facility not to have access to markets outside a persistently congested
area to sell the qualifying facility output or capacity.
(d)(1) For purposes of paragraphs (a)(1), (2), and (3) of this
section, there is a rebuttable presumption that a qualifying
cogeneration facility with a capacity at or below 20 megawatts does not
have nondiscriminatory access to the market.
(2) For purposes of paragraphs (a)(1), (2), and (3) of this
section, there is a rebuttable presumption that a qualifying small
power production facility with a capacity at or below 5 megawatts does
not have nondiscriminatory access to the market.
(3) Nothing in paragraphs (d)(1) through (3) of this section
affects the rights the rights or remedies of any party under any
contract or obligation, in effect or pending approval before the
appropriate State regulatory authority or non-regulated electric
utility on or before December 31, 2020, to purchase electric energy or
capacity from or to sell electric energy or capacity to a small power
production facility between 5 megawatts and 20 megawatts under this Act
(including the right to recover costs of purchasing electric energy or
capacity).
(4) For purposes of implementing paragraphs (d)(1) and (2) of this
section, the Commission will not be bound by the standards set forth in
Sec. 292.204(a)(2).
(e) Midcontinent Independent System Operator, Inc. (MISO), PJM
Interconnection, L.L.C. (PJM), ISO New England Inc. (ISO-NE), and New
York Independent System Operator, Inc. (NYISO) qualify as markets
described in paragraphs (a)(1)(i) and (ii) of this section, and there
is a rebuttable presumption that small power production facilities with
a capacity greater than 5 megawatts and cogeneration facilities with a
capacity greater than 20 megawatts have nondiscriminatory access to
those markets through Commission-approved open access transmission
tariffs and interconnection rules, and that electric utilities that are
members of such regional transmission organizations or independent
system operators (RTO/ISOs) should be relieved of the obligation to
purchase electric energy from the qualifying facilities. A qualifying
facility may seek to rebut this presumption by demonstrating, inter
alia, that:
(1) The qualifying facility has certain operational characteristics
that effectively prevent the qualifying facility's participation in a
market; or
(2) The qualifying facility lacks access to markets due to
transmission constraints. The qualifying facility may show that it is
located in an area where persistent transmission constraints in effect
cause the qualifying facility not to have access to markets outside a
persistently congested area to sell the qualifying facility output or
capacity.
(f) The Electric Reliability Council of Texas (ERCOT) qualifies as
a market described in paragraph (a)(3) of this section, and there is a
rebuttable presumption that small power production facilities with a
capacity greater than five megawatts and cogeneration facilities with a
capacity greater than 20 megawatts have nondiscriminatory access to
that market through Public Utility Commission of Texas (PUCT) approved
open access protocols, and that electric utilities that operate within
ERCOT should be relieved of the obligation to purchase electric energy
from the qualifying facilities. A qualifying facility may seek to rebut
this presumption by demonstrating, inter alia, that:
(1) The qualifying facility has certain operational characteristics
that effectively prevent the qualifying facility's participation in a
market; or
(2) The qualifying facility lacks access to markets due to
transmission constraints. The qualifying facility may show that it is
located in an area where persistent transmission constraints in
[[Page 54736]]
effect cause the qualifying facility not to have access to markets
outside a persistently congested area to sell the qualifying facility
output or capacity.
* * * * *
PART 375--THE COMMISSION
0
8. The authority citation for part 375 continues to read as follows:
Authority: 5 U.S.C. 551-557; 15 U.S.C. 717-717w, 3301-3432; 16
U.S.C. 791-825r, 2601-2645; 42 U.S.C. 7101-7352.
0
9. Amend Sec. 375.302 by revising paragraph (v) to read as follows:
Sec. 375.302 Delegations to the Secretary.
* * * * *
(v) Toll the time for action on requests for rehearing, and toll
the time for action on protested self-certifications and self-
recertifications of qualifying facilities.
The following will not appear in the Code of Federal Regulations.
United States of America Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
------------------------------------------------------------------------
Docket Nos.
------------------------------------------------------------------------
Qualifying Facility Rates and Requirements............ RM19-15-000
Implementation Issues Under the Public Utility AD16-16-000
Regulatory Policies Act of 1978......................
------------------------------------------------------------------------
(Issued July 16, 2020)
GLICK, Commissioner, dissenting in part:
1. I dissent in part from today's final rule (Final Rule \1\)
because it effectively guts the Commission's implementation of the
Public Utility Regulatory Policies Act (PURPA).\2\ The Commission's
basic responsibilities under PURPA are three-fold: (1) To encourage the
development of qualifying facilities (QFs); (2) to prevent
discrimination against QFs by incumbent utilities; and (3) to ensure
that the resulting rates paid by electricity customers remain just and
reasonable, in the public interest, and do not exceed the incremental
costs to the utility of alternative energy.\3\ I do not believe that
today's Final Rule satisfies those responsibilities. Instead, the Final
Rule raises as many questions as it answers, not least of which is the
long-term legal viability of an approach that does so little to
encourage QF development.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1\ Qualifying Facility Rates and Requirements Implementation
Issues Under the Public Utility Regulatory Policies Act of 1978,
Order No. 872, 172 FERC ] 61,041 (2020) (Final Rule).
\2\ Public Law 95-617, 92 Stat. 3117 (1978).
\3\ See 16 U.S.C. 824a-3(a)-(b) (2018).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
2. Although I have concerns about many of the individual changes
imposed by the Final Rule,\4\ I remain, on a broader level, dismayed
that the Commission is attempting to accomplish via administrative fiat
what Congress has repeatedly declined to do via legislation. I am
especially disappointed because Congress expressly provided the
Commission with a different avenue for ``modernizing'' our
administration of PURPA. The Energy Policy Act of 2005 gave the
Commission the authority to excuse utilities from their obligations
under PURPA where QFs have non-discriminatory access to competitive
wholesale markets.\5\ Had we pursued reforms based on those provisions,
rather than gutting our longstanding regulations, I believe we could
have reached a durable, consensus solution that would ultimately have
done more for all interested parties, even those that may celebrate the
immediate effects of this Final Rule.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\4\ Notwithstanding those concerns, I support certain aspects of
this Final Rule. First and foremost, I agree with the update to the
``one-mile'' rule, which prior to today provided an irrebuttable
presumption that resources located more than one mile apart are
separate QFs. In addition, I support requiring that QFs demonstrate
commercial viability before securing a legally enforceable
obligation with the relevant utility. Finally, I also support the
revision to allow stakeholders to protest a QF's self-certification.
\5\ Public Law 109-58, 1253, 119 Stat. 594 (2005).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
I. PURPA's Continuing Relevance Is an Issue for Congress To Decide
3. This proceeding began with a bang. My colleagues championed the
proposed rule as a ``truly significant'' action that would
fundamentally overhaul the Commission's implementation of PURPA.\6\ And
so it was. The NOPR proposed to alter almost every significant aspect
of the Commission's PURPA regulations, thereby transforming the
foundation on which the Commission had carried out its statutory
responsibility to ``encourage'' the development of QFs.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\6\ Sept. 2019 Commission Meeting Tr. at 8.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
4. I dissented from the NOPR in large part because I believe that
it is not the Commission's role to sit in judgment of a duly enacted
statute and determine whether it has outlived its usefulness. As I
explained, ``almost from the moment PURPA was passed, Congress began to
hear many of the arguments being used today to justify scaling the law
back.'' \7\ Congress, however, has seen fit to significantly amend
PURPA only once in its more-than-forty-year lifespan. As part of the
Energy Policy Act of 2005, Congress amended PURPA, leaving in place the
law's basic framework, while adding a series of provisions that allowed
the Commission to excuse utilities from its requirements in regions of
the country with sufficiently competitive wholesale energy markets.\8\
And while Congress considered numerous proposals to further reform the
law, it never saw fit to act on them.\9\ Against that background, I
could not support my colleagues' willingness to ``remove[ ] an
important debate from the halls of Congress and isolate[] it within the
Commission.'' \10\ Whatever your position on PURPA--and I recognize
views vary widely--``what should concern all of us is that resolving
these sorts of questions by regulatory edict rather than congressional
legislation is neither a durable nor desirable approach for developing
energy policy.'' \11\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\7\ Qualifying Facility Rates and Requirements Implementation
Issues Under the Public Utility Regulatory Policies Act of 1978,
Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 168 FERC ] 61,184 (2019) (NOPR)
(Glick, Comm'r, dissenting in part at P 3).
\8\ Public Law 109-58, 1253, 119 Stat. 594 (2005).
\9\ See Solar Energy Industries Association (SEIA) Comments at
11.
\10\ NOPR, 168 FERC ] 61,184 (Glick, Comm'r, dissenting in part
at P 4).
\11\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
5. Today's Final Rule retreats from much of the original rationale
used to support the NOPR, but the effect is the same: The Commission is
administratively gutting PURPA. Make no mistake, although the
Commission has dropped much of the NOPR preamble's opening screed
against PURPA's continuing relevance, this Final Rule is a full-
throated endorsement of the conclusion that PURPA has outlived its
usefulness. And while walking back the argument that PURPA is
antiquated may reduce the risk that this Final Rule is overturned on
appeal, that does not change the fact that today's Final Rule usurps
what should be Congress's proper role.
6. Throughout this proceeding, the Commission has been quick to
point to Congress's directive to from time to time
[[Page 54737]]
amend our regulations implementing PURPA.\12\ This Final Rule, however,
is a wholesale overhaul of the Commission's PURPA regulations that
reflects a deep skepticism of the need for the law we are charged with
implementing. I doubt that is what Congress had in mind when it gave us
responsibility for periodically updating our implementing regulations.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\12\ Final Rule, 172 FERC ] 61,041 at PP 24, 48, 54, 67, 296,
628; NOPR, 168 FERC ] 61,184 at PP 4, 16, 29, 155.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
II. The Commission's Proposed Reforms Are Inconsistent With Our
Statutory Mandate
7. PURPA directs the Commission to adopt such regulations as are
``necessary to encourage'' QFs,\13\ including by establishing rates for
sales by QFs that are just and reasonable and by ensuring that such
rates ``shall not discriminate'' against QFs.\14\ As explained below,
many of the changes adopted by the Commission in the Final Rule fail to
meet that standard. In addition, many of the reforms are unsupported--
or, in many cases, contradicted--by the evidence in the record.\15\
Accordingly, I believe today's Final Rule is not just poor public
policy, but also arbitrary and capricious agency action.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\13\ A QF is a cogeneration facility or a small power production
facility. See 18 CFR 292.101(b)(1) (2019).
\14\ 16 U.S.C. 824a-3(a)-(b).
\15\ Genuine Parts Co. v. EPA, 890 F.3d 304, 312 (D.C. Cir.
2018) (``[A]n agency cannot ignore evidence that undercuts its
judgment; and it may not minimize such evidence without adequate
explanation.'') (citations omitted); id. (``Conclusory explanations
for matters involving a central factual dispute where there is
considerable evidence in conflict do not suffice to meet the
deferential standards of our review.'' (quoting Int'l Union, United
Mine Workers v. Mine Safety & Health Admin., 626 F.3d 84, 94 (D.C.
Cir. 2010)).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
A. Avoided Cost
8. The Final Rule adopts two fundamental changes to how QF rates
are determined. First, and most importantly, it eliminates the
requirement that a utility must afford a QF the option to enter a
contract at a rate for energy that is either fixed for the duration of
the contract or determined at the outset--e.g., based on a forward
curve reflecting estimated prices over the term of the contract.\16\
Second, it presumptively allows states to set the rate for as-available
energy at the relevant locational marginal price (LMP) or a similarly
``competitive market price.'' \17\ The record in this proceeding does
not support either of those changes.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\16\ Final Rule, 172 FERC ] 61,041 at P 253.
\17\ Id. PP 151, 189, 211.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
i. Elimination of Fixed Energy Rate
9. Prior to today's Final Rule, a QF generally had two options for
selling its output to a utility. Under the first option, the QF could
sell its energy on an as-available basis and receive an avoided cost
rate calculated at the time of delivery. This is generally known as the
as-available option. Under the second option, a QF could enter into a
fixed-duration contract at an avoided cost rate that was fixed either
at the time the QF established a legally enforceable obligation (LEO)
or at the time of delivery. This is generally known as the contract
option. The ability to choose between both types of sale options played
an important role in fostering the development of a variety of QFs. For
example, the as-available option provided a way for QFs whose principal
business was not generating electricity, such as industrial
cogeneration facilities, to monetize their excess electricity
generation. The contract option, by contrast, provided QFs who were
principally in the business of generating electricity, such as small
renewable electricity generators, a stable option that would allow them
to secure financing. Together, the presence of these two options
allowed the Commission to satisfy its statutory mandate to encourage
the development of QFs and ensured that the rates they received were
non-discriminatory.
10. The Final Rule eliminates the requirement that states provide a
contract option that includes a fixed energy rate.\18\ Prior to this
proceeding, the Commission recognized time and again that fixed-price
contracts play an essential role in the financing of QF facilities,
making them a necessary element of any effort to encourage QF
development, at least in certain regions of the country.\19\ In
addition, fixed-price contracts have helped prevent discrimination
against QFs by ensuring that they are not structurally disadvantaged
relative to vertically integrated utilities that are guaranteed to
recover the costs of their prudently incurred investments through
retail rates.\20\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\18\ Id. P 253.
\19\ See, e.g., Small Power Production and Cogeneration
Facilities; Regulations Implementing Section 210 of the Public
Utility Regulatory Policies Act of 1978, Order No. 69, FERC Stats. &
Regs. ] 30,128, at 30,880, order on reh'g sub nom. Order No. 69-A,
FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 30,160 (1980), aff'd in part vacated in part,
Am. Elec. Power Serv. Corp. v. FERC, 675 F.2d 1226 (D.C. Cir. 1982),
rev'd in part sub nom. Am. Paper Inst. v. Am. Elec. Power Serv.
Corp., 461 U.S. 402 (1983). (justifying the rule on the basis of
``the need for certainty with regard to return on investment in new
technologies''); NOPR, 168 FERC ] 61,184 at P 63 (``The Commission's
justification for allowing QFs to fix their rate at the time of the
LEO for the entire term of a contract was that fixing the rate
provides certainty necessary for the QF to obtain financing.'');
Windham Solar LLC, 157 FERC ] 61,134, at P 8 (2016).
\20\ See, e.g., ELCON Comments at 21-22 (``More varible avoided
cost rates will result in unintended consequences that result in
less competitive conditions and may leave consumers worse off, as
utility self-builds do not face the same market risk exposure.
Pushing more market risk to QFs while utility assets remain
insulated from markets creates an investment risk asymmetry. This
puts QFs at a competitive disadvantage''); South Carolina Solar
Business Association Comments at 8 (``[A]s-available rates for QFs
in vertically-integrated states therefore discriminate against QFs
by requiring QFs to enter into contracts at substantially and
unjustifiably different terms than incumbent utilities.''); Southern
Environmental Law Center Supplement Comments, Docket No. AD16-16-
000, at 6-8 (Oct. 17, 2018) (explaining that vertically integrated
utilities in Indiana, Alabama, Virginia and Tennessee only offer
short-term rates to QFs); sPower Comments at 13; see also Statement
of Travis Kavulla, Docket No. AD16-16-000, at 2 (June 29, 2016).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
11. If anything, the record before us confirms the continuing
importance of fixed-price contracts. Numerous entities with experience
financing and developing QFs explain that a fixed revenue stream of
some sort is necessary to obtain the financing needed to develop a new
QF.\21\ The fixed revenue stream is particularly important because QFs
are overwhelmingly developed outside of the organized markets, meaning
that developers cannot necessarily obtain hedging contracts to create
the revenue predictability needed to obtain financing.\22\ And that is
why the Final Rule's parade of statistics about the growth of
renewables misses the point.\23\ It is true that, primarily in
[[Page 54738]]
organized markets, independently developed renewables are able to
develop without the entitlement to a fixed-price contract for energy
from the relevant utility.\24\ But the growth of renewables and their
financeability in organized markets tells us almost nothing about what
is required to sufficiently encourage QFs outside those markets.\25\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\21\ See, e.g., SEIA Comments at 29; North Carolina Attorney
General's Office Comments at 5; Con Ed Development Comments at 3;
South Carolina Solar Business Association Comments at 6; sPower
Comments at 11; Resources for the Future Comments at 6-7.
\22\ See, e.g., SEIA Comments at 29-30 (``As both Mr. Shem and
Mr. McConnell explain, financial hedge products are not available
outside of ISO/RTO markets.''); Resources for the Future Comments at
6-7 (``[W]hile hedge products do support wind and solar project
financing, they would not be suited for most QF projects. To hedge
energy prices, wind projects have used three products: bank hedges,
synthetic power purchase agreements (synthetic PPAs), and proxy
revenue swaps . . . . From U.S. project data for 2017 and 2018, the
smallest wind project securing such a hedge was 78 MW, and most
projects were well over 100 MW. Additionally, as hedges rely on
wholesale market access and liquid electricity trading, all of the
projects were in ISO regions.'') (emphasis added).
\23\ Harvard Electricity Law Comments at 22 (referring to a
similar statistical parade in the NOPR and observing that ``[a]ll
[the Commission] can actually conclude from this loosely connected
array of facts, data, and speculation is that some non-QF generators
are developed with variable-rate energy contracts. That unremarkable
conclusion has no bearing on whether repeal will discourage QF
development by `materially affect[ing] the ability of QFs to obtain
financing.' '' (citing NOPR, 168 FERC ] 61,184 at P 69)); SEIA
Comments at 30.
\24\ See Final Rule, 172 FERC ] 61,041 at P 340 (``EIA data
demonstrates that net generation of energy by non-utility owned
renewable resources in the United States grew by almost 700% between
2005 and 2018.''). Although independent power producers, renewable
or otherwise, within the RTO/ISO markets are not entitled to fixed
price contracts for energy as a matter of law, they generally do
rely on alternative tools, such as commodity hedges, to lock-in
energy revenue streams. See, e.g., EEI Comments at 36; sPower
Comments at 12.
\25\ In the logical leap of the year, the Commission notes that
in some areas of the country, unspecified resources are developed
with a fixed-price contract for capacity and a variable price for
energy and, separately, that renewables have grown nationwide more
than seven-fold between 2005 and 2018. Final Rule, 172 FERC ] 61,041
at P 340. From those disparate observations, the Commission
concludes that ``renewable resources are able to acquire financing
even without the right to require long-term fixed energy rates.''
Id. But nothing in the record suggests that that phenomenal growth
in renewables was at all the result of that bifurcated contract
structure. That, it should be clear, is not reasoned decisionmaking.
Cf. Nat'l Ass'n of Recycling Indus., Inc. v. Fed. Mar. Comm'n, 658
F.2d 816, 820 n.10 (D.C. Cir. 1980) (``We do not want, after all,
blithely to compare apples and oranges. Likewise, an agency should
also avoid unavailing comparisons of nonsubstitutes.''); see also
Commissioner Slaughter Comments at 4 (noting the ``widespread
geographic differentiation'' in renewable energy progress and
``barriers to independent renewable energy-based power producers'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
12. It would be one thing to eliminate the requirement to provide a
fixed-price option for energy rates for QFs that are entitled to a
fixed price for capacity. Although reasonable minds might disagree
about whether a fixed price for capacity alone is sufficient
encouragement, combining one with a variable price for energy would
provide at least some guaranteed revenue stream with which to finance
new development.\26\ Indeed, much of the Commission's justification for
eliminating the fixed-price contract option for energy rests on the
availability of a fixed-price contract option for capacity.\27\
Commission precedent, however, permits utilities to offer a capacity
rate of zero to QFs when the utility does not need incremental
capacity.\28\ That means that, as a result of this Final Rule, QF
developers will face the very real prospect of not receiving any fixed
revenue stream, whether for energy or capacity, in areas where they
also cannot secure hedging products or other mechanisms needed to
finance a new QF.\29\ It is hard for me to understand how the
Commission can, with a straight face, claim to be encouraging QF
development while at the same time eliminating the conditions necessary
to develop QFs in the regions where they are being built.\30\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\26\ See, e.g., SEIA Comments at 29 (``While securing financing
based on an As-Available Energy rate and a fixed capacity rate may
be a rare possibility in a few sub-markets across the country, as
Mr. Shem explains, it certainly is not the case in any state that
does not participate in an ISO/RTO market.'').
\27\ See Final Rule, 172 FERC ] 61,041 at P 36 (``This assertion
that the Commission has eliminated fixed rates for QFs is not
correct . . . . The NOPR thus made clear: under the proposed
revisions to Sec. 292.304(d), a QF would continue to be entitled to
a contract with avoided capacity costs calculated and fixed at the
time the LEO is incurred.'') (internal quotation marks omitted); id.
P 237 (``The Commission stated that these fixed capacity and
variable energy payments have been sufficient to permit the
financing of significant amounts of new capacity in the RTOs and
ISOs.'').
\28\ See, e.g., id. P 422 (citing to City of Ketchikan, Alaska,
94 FERC ] 61,293, at 62,061 (2001)).
\29\ See, e.g., Resources for the Future Comments at 6; SEIA
Comments at 30; Southeast Public Interest Organizations Comments at
12.
\30\ See Public Interest Organizations Comments at 10-11
(``Obviously, rules that have an effect of discouraging QFs cannot
be 'necessary to' encouraging them.''); see also Massachusetts
Attorney General Maura Healey Comments at 6 (``This action may
reduce investor confidence and discourage future development. That
outcome is a negative one for the Commonwealth and its
ratepayers.'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
13. The Commission sidesteps this point in responding that PURPA
does not require that QFs be financeable. That is true in a literal
sense; nothing in PURPA directs the Commission to ensure that at least
some QFs be financeable. But it does require the Commission to
encourage their development, which we have previously equated with
financeability.\31\ If the Commission is going to abandon that
standard, it must then explain why what is left of its regulations
provides the requisite encouragement--an explanation that is lacking
from this Final Rule, notwithstanding the Commission's repeated
assertions to the contrary.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\31\ See, e.g., Order No. 69, FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 30,128 at
30,880 (justifying the rule on the basis of ``the need for certainty
with regard to return on investment in new technologies''); NOPR,
168 FERC ] 61,184 at P 63 (``The Commission's justification for
allowing QFs to fix their rate at the time of the LEO for the entire
term of a contract was that fixing the rate provides certainty
necessary for the QF to obtain financing.'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
14. The Commission also does not sufficiently explain how
eliminating the fixed-price contract requirement is consistent with
PURPA's requirement that rates ``shall not discriminate against''
QFs.\32\ Vertically integrated utilities effectively receive guaranteed
fixed-price contracts through their rights to recover prudently
incurred investments. The equivalent right to receive fixed-price
contracts has to date proved an integral element of the Commission's
ability to satisfy PURPA's prohibition on discriminatory rates.\33\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\32\ 16 U.S. Code Sec. 824a-3(b)(2). Unlike provisions of the
Federal Power Act, PURPA prohibits any discrimination against QFs,
not just undue discrimination. See ELCON Comments at 21-22; South
Carolina Solar Business Alliance Comments at 7-8; sPower Comments at
13.
\33\ See supra n.20; Commissioner Slaughter Comments at 4.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
15. And yet this Final Rule fails to explain how eliminating the
fixed-price option is consistent with that prohibition or, moreover,
how permitting QFs to receive variable contract rates while vertically
integrated utilities receive fixed ones is consistent with the
Commission's obligation to promote QFs.\34\ Instead, the Commission
notes that, through so-called fuel adjustment clauses, vertically
integrated utilities' rates change as the price of fuel changes.\35\
The idea that those clauses, which ensure that utilities recover a
specific variable cost (i.e., their cost of fuel), is the same thing as
having your entire revenue exposed to variations in prevailing market
conditions is hogwash. The presence of fuel adjustment clauses in no
way suggests that vertically integrated utilities are subject to
anything remotely close to the level of revenue variation contemplated
in this Final Rule.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\34\ Public Interest Organizations Comments at 51 (``[L]imiting
QFs to contracts providing no price certainty for energy values,
while non-QF generation regularly obtains fixed price contracts and
utility-owned generation receives guaranteed cost recovery from
captive ratepayers, constitutes discrimination.'').
\35\ Final Rule, 172 FERC ] 61,041 at P 122.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
16. Finally, the Commission fails to explain why allegations of QF
rates exceeding a utility's actual avoided cost requires us to abandon
the Commission's long-held principles regarding certainty and
financing.\36\ As an initial matter, the Commission has recognized that
QF rates may exceed actual avoided costs, but, at the same time,
recognized that avoided cost rates might also turn out to be lower than
the electric utility's avoided costs over the course of the contract.
The Commission has reasoned that, ``in the long run, `overestimations'
and `underestimations' of avoided costs will balance out.'' \37\
However, when presented with a couple allegations that avoided costs
were overestimated,\38\ the Commission now concludes that that
possibility suggests it must abandon the fixed-energy rate
[[Page 54739]]
contract altogether. The Commission, however, makes no effort to
validate these allegations,\39\ or assess whether the overestimations
of avoided cost were, in fact, balanced out.\40\ It is arbitrary and
capricious to point to only half the picture in abandoning a forty-
year-old principle.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\36\ See supra n.19.
\37\ Order No. 69, FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 30,128 at 30,880.
\38\ Final Rule, 172 FERC ] 61,041 at PP 265, 268.
\39\ Id. PP 291, 293.
\40\ The Commission is quick to point to ``the precipitous
decline in natural gas prices'' starting in 2008 that may have
caused QF contracts fixed prior to that period to underestimate the
actual cost of energy. See, e.g., Final Rule, 172 FERC ] 61,041 at P
287). However, PURPA has been in place for forty years, and the
Commission does not wrestle with the magnitude of potential savings
conveyed to consumers from the fixed-price energy contracts that
locked-in low rates for consumers during the decades prior when
natural gas prices were several times higher. See Energy Information
Administration Total Energy, tbl. 9.10 (last viewed July 15, 2020),
https://www.eia.gov/totalenergy/data/browser/.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
ii. Rebuttable Presumption for Setting Avoided Cost at LMP and Similar
Measures
17. I also do not support the Commission's decision to treat LMP or
other ``competitive market prices'' as a presumptively reasonable
measure of an as-available avoided cost for energy.\41\ Liquid price
signals can be useful and transparent inputs and ought to be considered
in calculating an appropriate avoided-cost figure. But considering
those price signals in setting avoided cost is not the same thing as
presuming that LMP or similar measures are alone sufficient to
establish avoided cost. Many regions of the country--often the same
regions where the debates about PURPA are most heated--have not
established sufficiently competitive markets. In these regions it is
not clear from the record that the prices in, for example, a
neighboring RTO, are a representative measure of a utility's avoided
cost. In those less competitive markets, it simply does not make sense
to presume that LMP or other ``competitive market prices'' are a
representative measure of avoided cost, rather than one of many
criteria that should go into that determination.\42\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\41\ Final Rule, 172 FERC ] 61,041 at PP 151, 189, 211.
\42\ Congress itself seems to have contemplated that states
would not rely solely on spot market prices when establishing
avoided cost. H.R. Rep. No. 95-1750, at 7833 (1978) (``In
interpreting the term `incremental cost of alternative energy,' the
conferees expect that the Commission and the states may look beyond
the cost of alternative sources which are instantaneously available
to the utility.'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
18. For similar reasons, I share the concern of many commenters
that short-term or spot prices, such as LMP, may not reflect the long-
term marginal energy costs avoided by purchasing utilities, especially
outside of organized markets.\43\ Although the Commission revises the
NOPR's per se rule to be a rebuttable presumption, it nevertheless
plows ahead with the conclusion that LMP, and similar measures, reflect
a utility's avoided cost of energy. Where there is good reason to
believe that those measures do not actually reflect the long-term value
of energy that they are supposed to represent, it makes no sense to put
the burden on QFs to prove the point,\44\ rather than leaving the
burden with the proponents of using such measures.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\43\ Final Rule, 172 FERC ] 61,041 at n.163; Hydro Comments at
11; Southeast Public Interest Organizations Comments at 19; NIPPC,
CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 52, 55; Union of Concerned
Scientists Comments at 6. Take, for example, the Commission's
approval of the Mid-Columbia market hub price as presumptively
reflecting a utility's avoided cost for energy. See Final Rule, 172
FERC ] 61,041 at PP 180, 189. Notwithstanding explicit support for
this approach from the regulated utility industry, the Washington
Utilities and Transportation Commission which, when addressing Puget
Sound Energy's plan to increase wholesale purchases from the Mid-
Columbia market ``liquid hub'' to 1,600 MW, expressed a concern
about the regulated utility's overreliance on such wholesale market
pricing and directed them to pursue an alternative plan to eliminate
this ``excessive risk.'' That is the exact type of tension conveyed
in the record--i.e, that such competitive market prices may not
accurately reflect a utility's avoided cost, as approved by
regulators. See Washington UTC, Acknowledgment Letter Attachment,
Puget Sound Energy's 2017 Electric and Natural Gas Integrated
Resource Plan, Wash. UTC Docket Nos. UE-160918, UG-160919 (Revised
June 19, 2018); see NIPPC, CREA, REC, and OSEIA Comments at 56.
\44\ Final Rule, 172 FERC ] 61,041 at P 152.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
19. The Commission's presumptive approval of LMP and similar
measures is even more problematic when combined with the decision to
allow utilities to eliminate the fixed-price contract option. Following
this Final Rule, QFs may be reduced to relying solely on some synthetic
and highly variable measure of what spot prices should be in a
competitive market based on gas prices and heat rates, all while the
utilities whose costs the QF is avoiding recovers an effectively
guaranteed rate potentially in excess of this representative
``competitive market price.'' I am not persuaded that this approach
will satisfy our obligation to encourage QFs and to do so using rates
that are non-discriminatory across all regions of the country.
B. Rebuttable Presumption 20 MW to 5 MW
20. Following the Energy Policy Act of 2005, the Commission
established a rebuttable presumption that QFs with a capacity greater
than 20 MW operating in RTOs and ISOs have non-discriminatory access to
competitive markets, eliminating utilities' must-purchase obligation
from those resources.\45\ The Final Rule reduces the threshold for that
presumption from 20 MW to 5 MW. \46\ That is an improvement over the
NOPR, which--without any support whatsoever--proposed to lower that
threshold to 1 MW.\47\ But, even so, the reduced 5 MW threshold is
unsupported by the record and inadequately justified in today's Final
Rule.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\45\ New PURPA Section 210(m) Regulations Applicable to Small
Power Production and Cogeneration Facilities, Order No. 688, 117
FERC ] 61,078, at P 72 (2006), order on reh'g, Order No. 688-A, 119
FERC ] 61,305 (2007), aff'd sub nom. Am. Forest & Paper Ass'n v.
FERC, 550 F.3d 1179 (D.C. Cir. 2008); see 16 U.S.C. Sec. 824a-3(m).
\46\ Final Rule, 172 FERC ] 61,041 at P 625.
\47\ NOPR, 168 FERC ] 61,184 at P 126.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
21. When it originally established the 20 MW threshold, the
Commission pointed to an array of barriers that prevented resources
below that level from having truly non-discriminatory access to RTO/ISO
markets. Those barriers included complications associated with
accessing the transmission system through the distribution system (a
common occurrence for such small resources), challenges with reaching
distant off-takers, as well as ``jurisdictional differences, pancaked
delivery rates, and additional administrative procedures'' that
complicate those resources' ability to participate in those markets on
a level playing field.\48\ In just the last few years, the Commission
has recognized the persistence of those barriers ``that gave rise to
the rebuttable presumption that smaller QFs lack nondiscriminatory
access to markets.'' \49\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\48\ Order No. 688-A, 119 FERC ] 61,305 at PP 96, 103.
\49\ E.g., N. States Power Co., 151 FERC ] 61,110, at P 34
(2015).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
22. Nevertheless, the Final Rule abandons the 20 MW threshold based
on the conclusory assertion that ``it is reasonable to presume that
access to RTO/ISO markets has improved'' and it is, therefore,
``appropriate to update the presumption.'' \50\ No doubt markets have
improved. But a borderline-truism about maturing markets does not
explain how the barriers arrayed against small resources have
dissipated, why it is reasonable to ``presume'' that the remaining
barriers do not inhibit non-discriminatory access, or why 5 MW is
[[Page 54740]]
an appropriate new threshold for that presumption.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\50\ Final Rule, 172 FERC ] 61,041 at P 629 (``Over the last 15
years, the RTO/ISO markets have matured, market participants have
gained a better understanding of the mechanics of such markets and,
as a result, we find that it is reasonable to presume that access to
the RTO/ISO markets has improved and that it is appropriate to
update the presumption for smaller production facilities.'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
23. Instead of any such evidence, the Final Rule notes that the
Commission uses the 5 MW as a demarcating line for other rules applying
to small resources. Specifically, it points to the fact that resources
below 5 MW can use a ``fast-track'' interconnection process, whereas
larger ones must use the large generator interconnection
procedures.\51\ But the fact that the Commission used 5 MW as the cut
off in another context hardly shows that it is the right cut off to use
in this context.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\51\ Id. P 630.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
24. Lacking substantial evidence to support the 5 MW threshold, the
Commission falls back on a deferential standard of review.\52\ But
while judicial review of agency policymaking is deferential, it is not
toothless. The same cases on which the Commission relies require that,
when an agency's policy reversal ``rests upon factual findings that
contradict those which underlay its prior policy,'' the agency must
``provide a more detailed justification than what would suffice for a
new policy created on a blank slate.'' \53\ That is because reasoned
decisionmaking requires that, when an agency changes course, it must
provide ``a reasoned explanation . . . for disregarding facts and
circumstances that underlay or were engendered by the prior policy.''
\54\ For the foregoing reasons, the Commission has failed to produce
any such explanation, making its change of course arbitrary and
capricious.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\52\ Id. P 637 (citing FCC v. Fox Television, 556 U.S. 502, 515
(2009), for the proposition that an agency ``need not demonstrate to
a court's satisfaction that the reasons for the new policy are
better than the reasons for the old one; it suffices that the new
policy is permissible under the statute, that there are good reasons
for it, and that the agency believes it to be better, which the
conscious change of course adequately indicates.'').
\53\ Fox Television, 556 U.S. at 515; Advanced Energy Economy
Comments at 6.
\54\ Fox Television, 556 U.S. at 516; Advanced Energy Economy
Comments at 6-7.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
III. Environmental Review Under the National Environmental Policy Act
25. In contrast to the Commission's crowing over the significance
of its PURPA overhaul, the Final Rule describes the changes adopted as
merely corrective and clarifying in nature when it comes to conducting
an environmental review.\55\ In particular, the Commission contends
that ``the changes adopted in this final rule are required to ensure
continued future compliance of the PURPA Regulations with PURPA, based
on the changed circumstances found by the Commission in this final
rule.'' \56\ In other words, because the Commission believes that the
changes adopted are necessary to conform with the statute, they are
mere corrective changes, which, in turn, qualifies them for the
categorical exemption from any environmental review under NEPA, or so
the argument goes.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\55\ Under the National Environmental Policy Act (NEPA), the
Commission must consider whether its action associated with
rulemakings will have a significant impact on the environment. See
42 U.S.C. 4321 et seq.
\56\ Final Rule, 172 FERC ] 61,041 at P 722.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
26. But by that logic, any Commission action needed to comply with
our various statutory mandates--whether ``just and reasonable'' or the
``public interest''--would be deemed corrective in nature and,
therefore, excluded from environmental review. The Commission, however,
fails to point to any evidence suggesting that is what the Council on
Environmental Quality contemplated when it allowed for categorical
exemptions.
IV. The Way To Revise PURPA Is To Create More Competition, Not Less
27. It didn't have to be this way. When Congress reformed PURPA in
the 2005 Energy Policy Act amendments, it indicated an unmistakable
preference for using market competition as the off-ramp for utilities
seeking relief from their PURPA obligations.\57\ Those reforms directed
the Commission to excuse utilities from those obligations where QFs had
non-discriminatory access to RTO/ISO markets or other sufficiently
competitive constructs.\58\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\57\ 16 U.S.C. Sec. 824a-3(m).
\58\ See Order No. 688, 117 FERC ] 61,078 at P 8.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
28. This record contains numerous comments explaining how the
Commission could use those amendments as a way to ``modernize'' PURPA
in a manner that both promotes actual competition and reflects
Congress's unambiguous intent.\59\ For example, in a white paper
released prior to the NOPR, the National Association of Regulatory
Utility Commissioners (NARUC) urged the Commission to give meaning to
the 2005 amendments by establishing criteria by which a vertically
integrated utility outside of an RTO or ISO could apply to terminate
the must-purchase obligation if it conducts sufficiently competitive
solicitations for energy and capacity.\60\ Other groups, including
representatives of QF interests, submitted additional comments on how
an approach along those lines might work.\61\ Several parties commented
on those proposals.\62\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\59\ See Advanced Energy Economy Comments at 13; Industrial
Energy Consumers Comments at 13-14; EPSA Comments at 16.
\60\ National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners
Supplemental Comments, Docket No. AD16-16-00, Attach. A, at 8 (Oct.
17, 2018); id. (proposing the Commission's Edgar-Allegheny criteria
as a basis for evaluating whether a proposal was adequately
competitive).
\61\ See, e.g., SEIA Supplemental Comments, Docket No. AD16-16-
000 (Aug. 28, 2019).
\62\ See, e.g., Advanced Energy Economy Comments at 12; APPA
Comments at 29; Colorado Independent Energy Comments at 7; ELCON
Comments at 19; Public Interest Organizations Comments at 90; SEIA
Comments at 24; Xcel Comments at 11.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
It is a shame that the Commission has elected to administratively
gut its long-standing PURPA implementation regime, rather than pursuing
reform rooted in PURPA section 210(m), such as the NARUC proposal.
Pursuing an option along those lines could have produced a durable,
consensus solution to the issues before us. I continue to believe that
the way to modernize PURPA is to promote real competition, not to gut
the provisions that the Commission has relied on for decades out of
frustration that Congress has repeatedly failed to repeal the statute
itself.
For these reasons, I respectfully dissent in part.
Richard Glick,
Commissioner.
[FR Doc. 2020-15902 Filed 9-1-20; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6717-01-P