Increasing Consistency and Transparency in Considering Benefits and Costs in the Clean Air Act Rulemaking Process, 35612-35627 [2020-12535]
Download as PDF
35612
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 113 / Thursday, June 11, 2020 / Proposed Rules
methods, under Executive Order 12898
(59 FR 7629, February 16, 1994).
The SIP is not approved to apply on
any Indian reservation land or in any
other area where EPA or an Indian tribe
has demonstrated that a tribe has
jurisdiction. In those areas of Indian
country, the rule does not have tribal
implications as specified by Executive
Order 13175 (65 FR 67249, November 9,
2000), nor will it impose substantial
direct costs on tribal governments or
preempt tribal law.
List of Subjects in 40 CFR Part 52
Environmental protection, Air
pollution control, Carbon monoxide,
Incorporation by reference,
Intergovernmental relations, Lead,
Nitrogen dioxide, Ozone, Particulate
matter, Reporting and recordkeeping
requirements, Sulfur oxides, Volatile
organic compounds.
Authority: 42 U.S.C. 7401 et seq.
Dated: May 29, 2020.
Mary Walker,
Regional Administrator, Region 4.
[FR Doc. 2020–12536 Filed 6–10–20; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6560–50–P
ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION
AGENCY
40 CFR Part 83
[EPA–HQ–OAR–2020–00044; FRL 10010–
62–OAR]
RIN 2060–AU51
Increasing Consistency and
Transparency in Considering Benefits
and Costs in the Clean Air Act
Rulemaking Process
Environmental Protection
Agency (EPA).
ACTION: Notice of proposed rulemaking.
AGENCY:
The Environmental Protection
Agency (EPA) is proposing processes
that it would be required to undertake
in promulgating regulations under the
Clean Air Act (CAA) to ensure that
information regarding the benefits and
costs of regulatory decisions is provided
and considered in a consistent and
transparent manner. This proposed
rulemaking addresses, among other
things, issues raised in the June 13, 2018
advance notice of proposed rulemaking,
‘‘Increasing Consistency and
Transparency in Considering Costs and
Benefits in the Rulemaking Process,’’
and proposes how the concepts
described in that advance document
would be implemented in rulemakings
conducted by the EPA using its
authorities under the CAA. The EPA is
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with PROPOSALS
SUMMARY:
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:51 Jun 10, 2020
Jkt 250001
proposing to establish procedural
requirements governing the
development and presentation of
benefit-cost analyses (BCA), including
risk assessments used in the BCA, for
significant rulemakings conducted
under the CAA. Together, these
requirements would help ensure that
the EPA implements its statutory
obligations under the CAA, and
describes its work in implementing
those obligations, in a way that is
consistent and transparent.
DATES: Comments must be received on
or before July 27, 2020.
Public Hearing: The EPA will hold
one or more virtual public hearings on
this proposed rulemaking. These will be
announced in a separate Federal
Register publication that provides
details, including specific dates, times,
and contact information for these
hearings.
ADDRESSES: You may send comments,
identified by Docket ID No. EPA–HQ–
OAR–2020–00044, by any of the
following methods:
• Federal eRulemaking Portal:
https://www.regulations.gov/ (our
preferred method). Follow the online
instructions for submitting comments.
Instructions: All submissions received
must include the Docket ID No. EPA–
HQ–OAR–2020–00044 for this
rulemaking. Comments received may be
posted without change to https://
www.regulations.gov/, including any
personal information provided. For
detailed instructions on sending
comments and additional information
on the rulemaking process, see the
‘‘Public Participation’’ heading of the
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION section of
this document. Out of an abundance of
caution for members of the public and
our staff, the EPA Docket Center and
Reading Room was closed to public
visitors on March 31, 2020, to reduce
the risk of transmitting COVID–19. Our
Docket Center staff will continue to
provide remote customer service via
email, phone, and webform. We
encourage the public to submit
comments via https://
www.regulations.gov or email, as there
is a temporary suspension of mail
delivery to EPA, and no hand deliveries
are currently accepted. For further
information on EPA Docket Center
services and the current status, please
visit us online at https://www.epa.gov/
dockets.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: Leif
Hockstad, Office of Air Policy and
Program Support, Office of Air and
Radiation, Environmental Protection
Agency, Mail Code 6103A,1200
Pennsylvania Avenue NW, Washington,
PO 00000
Frm 00011
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
DC 20460; (202) 343–9432; email
address: hockstad.leif@epa.gov.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION:
Organization of this document. The
following outline is provided to aid in
locating information in this preamble.
I. Public Participation
II. General Information
A. Does this action apply to me?
B. What is the Agency’s authority for
taking this action?
C. What action is the Agency taking?
III. Background
IV. Rationale and Summary of the Proposed
Requirements
A. Preparation of Benefit-Cost Analyses for
Significant Regulations
B. Best Practices for the Development of
Benefit-Cost Analysis
C. Requirement for Additional
Presentations of BCA Results in
Rulemakings
V. Additional Considerations and Requests
for Comment
A. Specifying How BCA Results Should
Inform Regulatory Decisions
B. Other Areas of Solicitation for Public
Comment
VI. References
VII. Statutory and Executive Order Reviews
I. Public Participation
A. Written Comments
Submit your comments, identified by
Docket ID No. EPA–HQ–OAR–2020–
00044, at https://www.regulations.gov
(our preferred method), or the other
methods identified in the ADDRESSES
section. Once submitted, comments
cannot be edited or removed from the
docket. The EPA may publish any
comment received to its public docket.
Do not submit electronically any
information you consider to be
Confidential Business Information (CBI)
or other information whose disclosure is
restricted by statute. Multimedia
submissions (audio, video, etc.) must be
accompanied by a written comment.
The written comment is considered the
official comment and should include
discussion of all points you wish to
make. The EPA will generally not
consider comments or comment
contents located outside of the primary
submission (i.e. on the web, cloud, or
other file sharing system). For
additional submission methods, the full
EPA public comment policy,
information about CBI or multimedia
submissions, and general guidance on
making effective comments, please visit
https://www.epa.gov/dockets/
commenting-epa-dockets.
The EPA is temporarily suspending
its Docket Center and Reading Room for
public visitors to reduce the risk of
transmitting COVID–19. Written
comments submitted by mail are
temporarily suspended and no hand
E:\FR\FM\11JNP1.SGM
11JNP1
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 113 / Thursday, June 11, 2020 / Proposed Rules
deliveries will be accepted. Our Docket
Center staff will continue to provide
remote customer service via email,
phone, and webform. We encourage the
public to submit comments via https://
www.regulations.gov. For further
information and updates on EPA Docket
Center services, please visit us online at
https://www.epa.gov/dockets.
The EPA continues to carefully and
continuously monitor information from
the Centers for Disease Control and
Prevention (CDC), local area health
departments, and our Federal partners
so that we can respond rapidly as
conditions change regarding COVID–19.
B. Public Hearing
The EPA will hold one or more virtual
public hearings on this proposed
rulemaking. These will be announced in
a separate Federal Register publication
that provides details, including specific
dates, times, and contact information for
these hearings. Please note that EPA is
deviating from its typical approach
because the President has declared a
national emergency. Because of current
CDC recommendations, as well as state
and local orders for social distancing to
limit the spread of COVID–19, EPA
cannot hold in-person public meetings
at this time.
II. General Information
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with PROPOSALS
A. Does this action apply to me?
This proposed regulation does not
regulate the conduct or determine the
rights of any entity or individual outside
the Agency, as this action pertains only
to internal EPA practices. However, the
Agency recognizes that any entity or
individual interested in EPA’s
regulations may be interested in this
proposal. For example, this proposal
may be of particular interest to entities
and individuals concerned with how
EPA conducts benefit and cost analyses.
B. What is the Agency’s authority for
taking this action?
The Agency proposes to take this
action under the CAA using 42 U.S.C.
7601(a)(1). Section 301(a)(1) of the CAA
provides authority to the Administrator
‘‘to prescribe such regulations as are
necessary to carry out his functions’’
under the CAA. Such authority extends
to internal agency procedures that
increase the Agency’s ability to provide
consistency and transparency to the
public in regard to the rulemaking
process under the CAA. The EPA
solicits comment on whether additional
or alternative sources of authority are
appropriate bases for this proposed
regulation.
This is a proposed rulemaking of
agency organization, procedure or
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:51 Jun 10, 2020
Jkt 250001
practice. This proposed procedural rule
would not regulate any person or entity
outside the EPA and would not affect
the rights or obligations of outside
parties. As a rule of Agency procedure,
this rule is exempt from the notice and
comment requirements set forth in the
Administrative Procedure Act. See 5
U.S.C. 553(b)(A). Nonetheless, the
Agency voluntarily seeks comment
because it believes that the information
and opinions supplied by the public
will inform the Agency’s views.
The D.C. Circuit has explained that
‘‘the critical feature of a rule that
satisfies the so-called procedural
exception [to the APA’s notice and
comment requirements] is that it covers
agency actions that do not themselves
alter the rights or interests of parties
. . . .’’ James A. Hurson Assocs. v.
Glickman, 229 F.3d 277, 280 (D.C. Cir.
2000); National Mining Association v.
McCarthy, 758 F.3d 243 (D.C. Cir. 2014)
(holding that EPA’s interagency plan for
enhanced consultation and coordination
is a procedural rule because it does not
alter the rights or interests of parties,
although it may alter the manner in
which the parties present themselves or
their viewpoints to the Agency);
Batterton v. Marshall, 648 F.2d 708
(D.C. Cir. 1980) (‘‘The critical question
is whether the agency action jeopardizes
the rights and interests of parties.’’).
This rule would not regulate the
conduct or determine the rights of any
entity outside the federal government.
C. What action is the Agency Taking?
This proposed action consists of three
elements. First, the proposed regulation
provides that the EPA will prepare a
BCA for all future significant proposed
and final regulations under the CAA.
Second, the EPA proposes that the BCA
be developed using the best available
scientific information and in accordance
with best practices from the economic,
engineering, physical, and biological
sciences. Third, the EPA proposes
additional procedural requirements to
increase transparency in the
presentation of the BCA results, while
maintaining the standard practices of
measuring net benefits consistent with
E.O. 12866. Together, these
requirements would help ensure that
the EPA implements its statutory
obligations under the CAA in a way that
is consistent and transparent. In this
document, the EPA solicits comment on
all aspects of this proposal and how it
can best be implemented in accordance
with existing law and prior statements
of policy that have called for increasing
consistency and transparency. Each of
the key elements of the action is
discussed in more detail below,
PO 00000
Frm 00012
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
35613
followed by a summary of specific
solicitations for comment.
III. Background
As the EPA works to advance its
mission of protecting public health and
the environment, it seeks to ensure that
its analyses of regulatory decisions
provided to the public continue to be
rooted in sound, transparent and
consistent approaches to evaluating
benefits and costs.
The Supreme Court noted in Michigan
v. EPA that ‘‘[c]onsideration of cost
reflects the understanding that
reasonable regulation ordinarily
requires paying attention to the
advantages and the disadvantages of
agency decisions.’’ Michigan v. EPA,
135 U.S. 2699, 2707 (2015). Many
environmental statutes, including the
CAA, contemplate the consideration of
costs as part of regulatory decisionmaking in many instances. Several of
these statutes, including the CAA,
contain provisions that explicitly
require some form of cost consideration
when establishing a standard.
Additionally, several other provisions
use terminology that in context
implicitly direct the EPA to consider
costs, alone or in conjunction with
benefits and other factors. For example,
section 112(n)(1)(A) of the CAA directs
the Administrator to ‘‘regulate electric
utility steam generating units under
[section 112], if the Administrator finds
such regulation is appropriate and
necessary.’’ ‘‘Read naturally in the
present context, the phrase ‘appropriate
and necessary’ requires at least some
attention to cost.’’ Michigan, 135 S. Ct.
at 2707 (2015). Therefore, in light of the
varying statutory provisions in the CAA
that apply to or otherwise address cost
consideration, the Agency proposes to
provide analysis to the public that will
present all of the benefits and costs in
a consistent manner for all significant
CAA rulemakings.
Thorough and careful economic
analysis is informative for developing
sound environmental policies. High
quality economic analyses enhance the
effectiveness of environmental policy
decisions by providing policy makers
and the public with information needed
to systematically assess the likely
consequences of various actions or
options. BCA, a type of economic
analysis, can serve an integral
informative role in the regulatory
development process. In general terms,
a BCA is an evaluation of both the
benefits and costs to society as a result
of a policy and the difference between
the two (i.e., the calculation of net
benefits (benefits minus costs)). It
provides information about whether a
E:\FR\FM\11JNP1.SGM
11JNP1
35614
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 113 / Thursday, June 11, 2020 / Proposed Rules
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with PROPOSALS
policy change has the potential to
improve the aggregate well-being of
society.
The usefulness of BCA in informing
the development of environmental
regulations has been recognized both
within and outside government for
decades. As discussed below,
Presidential Executive Orders and
statutes have been in place for decades
formally requiring the preparation of
BCA in the development of major
Federal regulations, and the courts have
examined the use of BCA in several
regulatory contexts. In addition, the
usefulness of formal BCA in informing
regulatory policy debates on protecting
and improving public health, safety, and
the natural environment has been
emphasized in the academic literature.
For example, as explained in seminal
work by prominent economists Arrow et
al. (1996a, 1996b), BCA ‘‘can provide an
exceptionally useful framework for
consistently organizing disparate
information, and in this way, it can
greatly improve the process and, hence,
the outcome of policy analysis. If
properly done, BCA can be of great help
to agencies participating in the
development of environmental
regulations . . .’’ (1996b). Arrow et al.
recommend that ‘‘Benefit-cost analysis
should be required for all major
regulatory decisions,’’ and that ‘‘the
precise definition of ‘major’ requires
judgment.’’
Benefit-cost analyses have been an
integral part of executive branch
rulemaking for decades. Presidents
since the 1970s have issued executive
orders requiring agencies to conduct
analysis of the economic consequences
of regulations as part of the rulemaking
development process. President Ford’s
1974 Executive Order (E.O.) 11821
required government agencies to
prepare inflation impact statements
before issuing major regulations.1 These
inflation impact statements essentially
turned into benefit-cost analyses based
on the understanding that a regulation
would not be truly inflationary unless
its costs to society exceeded the benefits
it produced,2 and the E.O. was renamed
as Economic Impact Statements with
E.O. 11949 in 1976.3 President Carter’s
1978 E.O. 12044, Improving
Government Regulations, included
1 Executive Order 11821 — Inflation Impact
Statements, Federal Register, Vol. 39, No. 231—
Friday, November 29, 1974 (pages 41501–41502).
2 https://obamawhitehouse.archives.gov/omb/
inforeg_chap1#tnfrp.
3 Executive Order 11949—Economic Impact
Statements, Federal Register, Vol. 42, No. 3—
Wednesday, January 5, 1977 (page 1017). https://
www.govinfo.gov/content/pkg/FR-1977-01-05/pdf/
FR-1977-01-05.pdf.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:51 Jun 10, 2020
Jkt 250001
formal requirements for conducting
regulatory analysis at a minimum ‘‘for
all regulations which will result in (a)
an annual effect on the economy of $100
million or more; or (b) a major increase
in costs or prices for individual
industries, levels of government or
geographic regions.’’ 4 Regulatory
analyses under E.O. 12044 were
required to contain ‘‘a succinct
statement of the problem; a description
of the major alternative ways of dealing
with the problem that were considered
by the agency; an analysis of the
economic consequences of each of these
alternatives and a detailed explanation
of the reasons for choosing one
alternative over the others.’’
In 1981, President Reagan issued E.O.
12291, Federal Regulation, which
imposed the first requirements for
conducting formal benefit-cost analysis
in the development of new major
Federal regulations. Among its
provisions, it explicitly required that:
‘‘(a) Administrative decisions shall be
based on adequate information
concerning the need for and
consequences of proposed government
action; (b) Regulatory action shall not be
undertaken unless the potential benefits
to society for the regulation outweigh
the potential costs to society; (c)
Regulatory objectives shall be chosen to
maximize the net benefits to society; (d)
Among alternative approaches to any
given regulatory objective, the
alternative involving the least net cost to
society shall be chosen; and (e)
Agencies shall set regulatory priorities
with the aim of maximizing the
aggregate net benefits to society, taking
into account the condition of the
particular industries affected by
regulations, the condition of the
national economy, and other regulatory
actions contemplated for the future.’’
Under E.O. 12291, major regulations
included ‘‘any regulation that is likely
to result in: (1) An annual effect on the
economy of $100 million or more; (2) A
major increase in costs or prices for
consumers, individual industries,
Federal, State, or local government
agencies, or geographic regions; or (3)
Significant adverse effects on
competition, employment, investment,
productivity, innovation, or on the
ability of United States-based
enterprises to compete with foreignbased enterprises in domestic or export
markets.’’ 5
4 Executive Order 12044—Improving Government
Regulations, Federal Register, Vol. 43, No. 58—
Friday, March 24, 1978 (pages 12659–12670).
5 https://www.archives.gov/federal-register/
codification/executive-order/12291.html.
PO 00000
Frm 00013
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
In 1993, E.O. 12291 was revoked and
replaced by President Clinton’s E.O.
12866, Regulatory Planning and Review,
which is still in effect today. E.O. 12866
requires that for all significant
regulatory actions pursuant to Section
3(f), an agency provide ‘‘an assessment
of the potential costs and benefits of the
regulatory action, including an
explanation of the manner in which the
regulatory action is consistent with a
statutory mandate . . .’’ For regulatory
actions meeting criteria listed under
Section 3(f)(1)—that is, any regulatory
action that is ‘‘likely to result in a rule
that may . . . have an annual effect on
the economy of $100 million or more or
adversely affect in a material way the
economy, a sector of the economy,
productivity, competition, jobs, the
environment, public health or safety, or
State, local, or tribal governments or
communities’’—E.O. 12866 further
requires that this assessment include a
quantification of benefits and costs to
the extent feasible. In addition, E.O.
12866 states that, to the extent
permitted by law, agencies ‘‘should
assess both the costs and the benefits of
the intended regulation and, recognizing
that some costs and benefits are difficult
to quantify, propose or adopt a
regulation only upon a reasoned
determination that the benefits of the
intended regulation justify its costs’’;
‘‘in choosing among alternative
regulatory approaches . . . should
select those approaches that maximize
net benefits (including potential
economic, environmental, public health
and safety, and other advantages;
distributive impacts; and equity), unless
a statute requires another regulatory
approach’’; and that ‘‘[e]ach agency
shall base its decisions on the best
reasonably obtainable scientific,
technical, economic, and other
information concerning the need for,
and consequences of, the intended
regulation.’’
In 1995, the Unfunded Mandates
Reform Act of 1995 (UMRA) included
analytical requirements for all
regulatory actions that include federal
mandates ‘‘that may result in the
expenditure by State, local, and tribal
governments, in the aggregate, or by the
private sector, of $100 million or more
(adjusted annually for inflation) in any
one year.’’ An action contains a federal
mandate if it imposes an enforceable
duty on state, local or tribal
governments, or the private sector. The
analytical requirements under UMRA
are similar to the analytical
requirements under E.O. 12866, and
thus the same analysis may permit
E:\FR\FM\11JNP1.SGM
11JNP1
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with PROPOSALS
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 113 / Thursday, June 11, 2020 / Proposed Rules
compliance with both analytical
requirements.
More recent Executive Orders also
reaffirm the requirements and principles
in E.O. 12866. The former
Administration’s E.O. 13563, issued in
2011 and also still in effect today,
reaffirms the requirements and other
principles and definitions in E.O. 12866
and embraces benefit-cost analysis: ‘‘In
applying these principles, each agency
is directed to use the best available
techniques to quantify anticipated
present and future benefits and costs as
accurately as possible.’’ 6 More recently,
this Administration’s E.O. 13777, issued
in 2017, directs agencies to identify
regulations that ‘‘impose costs that
exceed benefits.’’ 7 E.O. 13783, also
issued in 2017, similarly reaffirms the
importance of benefit-cost analysis: ‘‘In
order to ensure sound regulatory
decision making, it is essential that
agencies use estimates of costs and
benefits in their regulatory analyses that
are based on the best available science
and economics.’’ 8
The Office of Management and
Budget’s (OMB’s) Circular A–4 (OMB
2003), which remains in effect today,
provides guidance to Federal agencies
on the development of regulatory
analysis as required under E.O. 12866
and a variety of related authorities.9 In
developing Circular A–4, OMB first
developed a draft that was subject to
public comment, interagency review,
and external peer review. As
summarized in E.O. 13783, ‘‘. . . OMB
Circular A–4 . . . was issued after peer
review and public comment and has
been widely accepted for more than a
decade as embodying the best practices
for conducting regulatory cost-benefit
analysis.’’ 10 The document encourages
transparency in practices, including the
expression of costs and benefits in
monetary units that allow for the
evaluation of ‘‘incremental benefits and
costs of successively more stringent
regulatory alternatives’’ such that an
agency can ‘‘maximize net benefits.’’ 11
EPA’s Guidelines for Preparing
Economic Analyses (hereafter, the
Guidelines) 12 complements Circular A–
4 by providing the Agency with more
detailed peer-reviewed guidance on
how to conduct BCA and other types of
economic analyses for both
environmental regulatory actions and
non-regulatory management strategies,
with the intent of improving compliance
with E.O. 12866 and other executive
orders and statutory requirements (e.g.,
Small Business Regulatory Enforcement
Fairness Act of 1996 provisions). The
Guidelines are updated periodically—
building on work issued in 1983 (then
titled Guidelines for Performing
Regulatory Impact Analysis), 2000, and
most recently in 2010—to account for
growth and development of economic
tools and practices. The Guidelines
establish a scientific framework for
analyzing the benefits, costs, and other
economic impacts of regulations and
policies, including assessing the
distribution of costs and benefits among
various segments of the population. In
addition to presenting the wellestablished scientific foundations for
economic analysis, they incorporate
recent advances in theoretical and
applied work in the field of
environmental economics. Updates of
the Guidelines are led by the EPA’s
National Center for Environmental
Economics (NCEE) in consultation with
economists from across the Agency and
OMB. All chapters undergo an external
peer review, either through EPA’s
Science Advisory Board or through
independent reviews by external
experts, prior to be being finalized.13
Given the history described above
pertaining to the use of BCA by
executive agencies, and given that
several statutes, including the CAA,
include provisions that require some
form of cost consideration, the federal
courts have also developed significant
case law regarding regulatory cost
consideration and the usefulness of
BCA. This case law addresses when,
and if, such use is required or
permissible and how it may be
employed in reasoned decision-making.
As a general matter, while certain
6 https://obamawhitehouse.archives.gov/thepress-office/2011/01/18/executive-order-13563improving-regulation-and-regulatory-review.
7 Enforcing the Regulatory Reform Agenda (82 FR
12285, March 1, 2017).
8 https://www.govinfo.gov/content/pkg/FR-201703-31/pdf/2017-06576.pdf.
9 https://obamawhitehouse.archives.gov/omb/
circulars_a004_a-4/. Circular A–4 refines and
replaces OMB’s ‘‘best practices’’ document of 1996,
which was issued as a guidance in 2000 and
reaffirmed in 2001. All these versions of the 1996
document were superseded by Circular A–4.
10 https://www.govinfo.gov/content/pkg/FR-201703-31/pdf/2017-06576.pdf.
11 https://obamawhitehouse.archives.gov/omb/
circulars_a004_a-4/.
12 https://www.epa.gov/environmentaleconomics/guidelines-preparing-economicanalyses.
13 The EPA is in the process of a periodic update
of the Guidelines. The EPA anticipates that among
the changes within this update, the current Section
9.2.3.3, ‘‘Impacts on employment’’, will be replaced
with a discussion based on more recent literature
and feedback from the Economy Wide Modeling
Science Advisory Board Panel. For more details
regarding Chapter 9, see: https://www.epa.gov/sites/
production/files/2017-09/documents/ee-056809.pdf. For more details regarding the update of the
Guidelines in general, see: https://yosemite.epa.gov/
sab/sabproduct.nsf//LookupWebProjectsCurrent
BOARD/30D5E59E8DC91C2285258403006
EEE00?OpenDocument.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:51 Jun 10, 2020
Jkt 250001
PO 00000
Frm 00014
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
35615
statutory provisions may prohibit
reliance on BCA or other methods of
cost consideration in decision making,14
such provisions do not preclude the
Agency from providing additional
information regarding a proposed or
final rule to the public. For example,
while the CAA prohibits the EPA from
considering cost when establishing
requisite National Ambient Air Quality
Standards (NAAQS) for criteria
pollutants,15 the EPA nonetheless
provides Regulatory Impact Analyses
(RIAs) 16 to the public for these
rulemakings.17 The agency believes that
the information provided as a result of
the procedural requirements of this
proposal, if finalized, would increase
transparency and consistency across
CAA rulemakings; would provide the
public with additional information in
the CAA rulemaking process; and would
provide the Agency with supplemental
information for potential use by the
Agency when it is appropriate to be
considered. Whether the Agency utilizes
any information produced as a result of
these procedural requirements would be
determined by the statutes and
regulations governing particular
subsequent rulemakings. Any such
information would be in addition to the
information provided by other
methodologies and analyses as directed
by specific CAA statutes and
regulations.
The Supreme Court has held that
agencies may conduct and consider a
BCA even when a statute does not
explicitly require one. In Entergy Corp.
v. Riverkeeper, Inc., 556 U.S. 208, 222–
224 (2009), the Supreme Court clarified
that neither American Textile Mfrs. Inst.
v. Donovan, 452 U.S. 490 (1981)
(American Textile Mfrs.) nor Whitman
v. Am. Trucking Ass’ns, 531 U.S. 457
(2001) (American Trucking), stands for
the broad proposition that statutory
silence in regard to BCA always implies
prohibition of BCA. Concluding that the
EPA is permitted to use BCA in
determining the content of regulations
promulgated under Clean Water Act
section 1326(b). The Court reasoned
14 See, e.g., Whitman v. Am. Trucking Ass’ns, 531
U.S. 457 (2001) (holding that Section 109(b) of the
CAA unambiguously barred cost considerations
when setting the National Ambient Air Quality
Standards.
15 Id.
16 A regulatory impact analysis, or ‘‘regulatory
analysis’’ for brevity, as prepared under E.O. 12866,
consists of a benefit-cost analysis and any related
cost-effectiveness analyses and assessments of
economic and distributional impacts (OMB 2003).
17 See, e.g., U.S. EPA, Regulatory Impact Analysis
of the Proposed Revisions to the National Ambient
Air Quality Standards for Ground-Level Ozone
(2014), https://www3.epa.gov/ttn/ecas/regdata/
RIAs/20141125ria.pdf.
E:\FR\FM\11JNP1.SGM
11JNP1
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with PROPOSALS
35616
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 113 / Thursday, June 11, 2020 / Proposed Rules
‘‘that [CWA] § 1326(b)’s silence is meant
to convey nothing more than a refusal
to tie the agency’s hands as to whether
cost-benefit analysis should be used,
and if so to what degree.’’ Id. at 222; see
also id. at 212, 219–20, 226.
The Supreme Court noted that its
decisions in American Trucking and
American Textile Mfrs. ‘‘do not
undermine this conclusion.’’ 556 U.S. at
223. The Court highlighted that in
American Trucking, it had held that the
text of section 109 of the Clean Air Act,
‘‘interpreted in its statutory and
historical context . . . unambiguously
bars cost considerations’’ when air
quality standards are set pursuant to
that provision. American Trucking, 531
U.S. at 471, quoted in Entergy Corp., 556
U.S. at 223. The Entergy Corp. Court
further elaborated that ‘‘[t]he relevant
’statutory context’ [in American
Trucking] included other provisions in
the [CAA] that expressly authorized
consideration of costs, whereas § 109
did not.’’ 556 U.S. at 233. The Court
concluded that American Trucking
‘‘stands for the rather unremarkable
proposition that sometimes statutory
silence, when viewed in context, is best
interpreted as limiting agency
discretion.’’ 556 U.S. at 223. The Court
further noted that in American Textile,
the Court had relied, in part, on the
absence of mention of BCA in the
statute to hold that the agency was not
required to conduct a BCA when setting
certain health and safety standards. 556
U.S. at 223. ‘‘[U]nder Chevron, that an
agency is not required to [engage in
cost-benefit analysis] does not mean that
an agency is not permitted to do so.’’ Id.
Thus, the Supreme Court has confirmed
that a statute need not have explicitly
required that the agency conduct a BCA
in its decision-making process for the
agency to do so.
The Supreme Court additionally
acknowledged in Entergy Corp. that
‘‘whether it is ‘reasonable’ to bear a
particular cost may well depend on the
resulting benefits.’’ 556 U.S. at 225–226.
This concept was further elaborated
upon by the Court in Michigan v. EPA,
which held, in the context of the term
‘‘appropriate and necessary’’ contained
in Section 112(n)(1)(A) of the CAA, that
the term required consideration of cost.
135 S. Ct. 2699, 2706 (2015). In doing
so, the Supreme Court stated that ‘‘[o]ne
would not say that it is even rational,
never mind ‘appropriate,’ to impose
billions of dollars in economic costs in
return for a few dollars in health or
environmental benefits’’, concluding
that ‘‘[n]o regulation is ‘appropriate’ if it
does significantly more harm than
good.’’ Id. at 2707. The D.C. Circuit
recently echoed this concept in Mingo
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:51 Jun 10, 2020
Jkt 250001
Logan Coal Co. v. EPA. While the D.C.
Circuit panel ultimately concluded that
the cost issue had been forfeited by
petitioners, in response to then Judge
Kavanaugh’s dissent which argued that
cost consideration should be required,
the panel stated, ‘‘[i]ndeed, we do not
quibble with his general premise—and
that of the many legal luminaries he
cites—that an agency should generally
weigh the costs of its action against its
benefits.’’ 829 F.3d 710, 723 (D.C. Cir.
2016). In general, when cost
consideration is either required or
permitted by the CAA, the courts have
not mandated a specific type of cost
consideration but have granted the
Agency broad discretion in determining
its methodology. Michigan, 135 S. Ct. at
2711 (‘‘We need not and do not hold
that the law unambiguously required
the Agency, when making this
preliminary estimate, to conduct a
formal cost-benefit analysis in which
each advantage and disadvantage is
assigned a monetary value. It will be up
to the Agency to decide (as always,
within the limits of reasonable
interpretation) how to account for
cost.’’); see also Sierra Club v. Costle,
657 F.2d 298, 345 (D.C. Cir. 1981)
(‘‘[S]ection 111(a) explicitly instructs
the EPA to balance multiple concerns
when promulgating a NSPS.’’); id. at 321
(‘‘The text gives the EPA broad
discretion to weigh different factors in
setting the standard.’’); Lignite Energy
Council v. EPA, 198 F.3d 930, 933 (D.C.
Cir. 1999) (‘‘Because section 111 [of the
CAA] does not set forth the weight that
[should be] assigned to each of these
factors, we have granted the agency a
great degree of discretion in balancing
them’’); Husqvarna AB v. EPA, 254 F.3d
195, 200 (D.C. Cir. 2001) (‘‘Section 213
[of the CAA] . . . simply directs the
EPA to consider cost. . . . Because
section 213 does not mandate a specific
method of cost analysis, we find
reasonable the EPA’s choice to consider
costs on the per ton of emissions
removed basis.’’).
Additionally, lower courts have noted
the usefulness of BCA and have utilized
the information provided therein to
inform their analysis when reviewing
agency regulations. Several of these
cases utilize information from agencycreated BCAs and/or RIAs as evidence
that an agency ignored alternatives or
acted in an arbitrary and capricious
manner when taking action.
For example, in Advocates for
Highway and Auto Safety v. FMCSA,
429 F.3d. 1136 (D.C. Cir. 2005), the D.C.
Circuit relied in part on a BCA in
invalidating, as arbitrary and capricious,
a final rule promulgated by Federal
Motor Carrier Safety Administration
PO 00000
Frm 00015
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
(FMCSA) intended to ensure that
drivers of commercial motor vehicles
received adequate training. In its
analysis, the D.C. Circuit highlighted an
incongruity between methods of
training shown to be effective and the
final rule, noting that ‘‘[f]rom a purely
economic perspective, the agency’s
disregard of the Adequacy Report
[containing a BCA] is baffling in light of
the evidence in the record.’’ Id. at 1146.
The D.C. Circuit pointed to a training
regimen that ‘‘according to the agency’s
own calculations, [would] produce
benefits far in excess of costs.’’ Id.
Noting the agency’s findings that ‘‘the
program’s estimated 10–year cost of
between $4.19 billion to $4.51 billion
would yield a benefit ranging from $5.4
billion to $15.27 billion, depending on
analytic assumptions,’’ the court
concluded that the BCA for the rule
‘‘lends no support to FMCSA’s position.
In the final rule, FMCSA says
practically nothing about the projected
benefits.’’ Id.;
In Public Citizen, Inc. v. Mineta, 340
F.3d 39 (2nd Cir. 2003), the Second
Circuit determined that a National
Highway Traffic Safety Administration
(NHTSA) rule regarding tire pressure
monitoring system (TPMS) requirements
was arbitrary and capricious, as the
NHTSA BCA showed that alternatives
would be safer and more cost-effective.
The court stated that it may ‘‘be difficult
to weigh economic costs against safety
benefits. But the difficulty of the task
does not relieve the agency of its
obligation to perform it under [certain
vehicle safety laws] and State Farm.’’ Id.
at 58 (citing Motor Vehicles Mfrs. Ass’n
v. State Farm Mut. Auto. Ins. Co., 463
U.S. 29 (1983)). The Second Circuit
observed that NHTSA ‘‘instead, presents
us with a rulemaking record that does
not explain why the costs saved were
worth the benefits sacrificed.’’ Id. The
court noted that the BCA ‘‘discloses that
the added cost for a system that worked
all of the time, rather than half of the
time, was less than $10 per car, and that
the adoption of the four-tire, 25 percent
standard alone was the most cost
effective means of preventing crashes
caused by significantly under-inflated
tires.’’ Id.
Finally, in NRDC v. EPA, 824 F.2d
1258 (1st Cir. 1987), the First Circuit
vacated, in part, and remanded rules for
long-term disposal of high-level
radioactive waste under Nuclear Waste
Policy Act of 1982 based in part on the
Agency’s selection of a 1,000-year
design criterion rather than a longerterm one. The court determined that it
was unreasonable agency action to not
adopt cheap methods of increasing
protections. In doing so, the court
E:\FR\FM\11JNP1.SGM
11JNP1
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 113 / Thursday, June 11, 2020 / Proposed Rules
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with PROPOSALS
observed that ‘‘[l]ikewise, EPA’s Final
[RIA] of 40 CFR part 191 demonstrates
that more rigorous site selection could
produce sites with such impermeable
geologic media that compliance with the
individual protections for a much longer
duration would not even require the
extra cost of ‘very good’ engineered
canisters.’’ Id. at 1289.
With this history in mind as a
backdrop and following E.O. 13777
noted above, the EPA is proposing to
establish requirements to ensure that the
EPA consistently assesses the costs and
benefits of significant CAA rules. The
EPA opened a public docket 18 in April
2017 to solicit feedback and identify
regulations that ‘‘impose costs that
exceed benefits.’’ Among the public
comments received, a large cross-section
of stakeholders stated that the agency
either underestimated costs,
overestimated benefits, or evaluated
benefits and costs inconsistently in its
rulemakings. Per E.O. 13777 and based
on these public comments, the EPA
decided to take further action to
evaluate opportunities for reform.
In June 2018, the EPA issued an
Advance Notice of Proposed
Rulemaking (ANPRM), ‘‘Increasing
Consistency and Transparency in
Considering Costs and Benefits in the
Rulemaking Process’’ (83 FR 27524,
June 13, 2018), to solicit public input on
potential approaches for increasing
consistency and transparency in how
the EPA considers benefits and costs in
the rulemaking process. Informed by the
public comments received on that
ANPRM, on May 13, 2019, the
Administrator issued a memorandum 19
to EPA’s Assistant Administrators
announcing the intention to propose
statute-specific rules that outline how
consistency and transparency concepts
will be implemented in future
rulemakings. The memorandum
outlined the following principles for
developing these regulatory proposals,
consistent with applicable laws and
regulations: Ensuring that the Agency
balances benefits and costs in regulatory
decision-making; increasing consistency
in the interpretation of statutory
terminology; providing transparency in
the weight assigned to various factors in
regulatory decisions; and promoting
adherence to best practices in
18 See EPA, Evaluation of Existing Regulations (82
FR 17793). All public comments are accessible
online in our docket on the Regulations.gov website
identified by Docket ID No. EPA–HQ–OA–2017–
0190.
19 Available at: https://www.epa.gov/
environmental-economics/administrator-wheelermemorandum-increasing-consistency-andtransparency.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:51 Jun 10, 2020
Jkt 250001
conducting the technical analysis used
to inform decisions.
This proposed rulemaking is the first
statute-specific rulemaking in this effort.
The EPA is proposing to codify the
procedural requirements governing the
development of BCA, including risk
assessments used as inputs to the BCA,
for significant rulemakings conducted
under the CAA, and proposes additional
procedural requirements to increase
transparency in the presentation of the
benefits resulting from significant CAA
regulations. Together, these
requirements would ensure a consistent
approach to the EPA’s CAA benefit-cost
analyses under the CAA and would
provide transparency by requiring the
generation of relevant information in all
significant rulemakings.
IV. Rationale and Summary of the
Proposed Requirements
A. Preparation of Benefit-Cost Analyses
for Significant Regulations
The EPA seeks to codify the practice
of preparing BCAs in the development
of future significant CAA regulations.
Specifically, EPA proposes that all
future significant proposed and final
regulations promulgated under the
Clean Air Act be accompanied by a
BCA. The EPA proposes to define a
significant regulation as a proposed or
final regulation that is determined to be
a ‘‘significant regulatory action’’
pursuant to E.O. 12866 Section 3(f) or is
otherwise designated as significant by
the Administrator. Regulations meeting
either of these factors are generally
those that the EPA anticipates would
have the largest annual impact on the
economy (i.e., greater than $100 million)
as well as those that are important to
analyze for other policy reasons. For
example, a rule projected to have less
than a $100 million annual effect on the
economy could disproportionately affect
a single industry, population subgroup,
or geographic area. Such rules, or ones
that are notably novel or significant for
other policy reasons, would benefit from
rigorous analysis to inform the public
and decision makers about the
magnitude and disposition of both their
benefits and costs on affected entities.
B. Best Practices for the Development of
Benefit-Cost Analysis
In response to the ANPRM, the EPA
received comments from a wide range of
stakeholders emphasizing the
importance of conducting BCA in
accordance with best practices from the
economic, engineering, physical, and
biological sciences. One theme raised by
some commenters was that there is
inadequate adherence to existing EPA
PO 00000
Frm 00016
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
35617
and OMB guidance for how to conduct
BCA. Some commenters pointed to
recent CAA regulatory BCAs conducted
pursuant to E.O. 12866 as examples of
a lack of transparency or improper
analytic assumptions. As one example,
some commenters contend that some
BCAs have double-counted benefits that
arise from another regulation. The EPA
agrees that there is a risk of such a
misestimation if the pollution
concentration levels resulting from
existing regulations are not carefully
accounted for in the baseline of the
analysis. In other words, this type of
double-counting can be avoided if the
Agency follows the best practices for
BCA of correctly specifying the baseline.
Several commenters recommended that
the EPA issue binding procedural
requirements to ensure transparency
and consistent adherence to best
practices for BCA. This proposed
rulemaking seeks to ensure consistent
adherence to best practices for BCA of
future CAA regulations by codifying
these requirements into regulation. The
EPA proposes that BCAs for significant
proposed and final CAA regulations be
developed in accordance with the best
available scientific information and best
practices from the economic,
engineering, physical, and biological
sciences. Specifically, the EPA proposes
to codify into regulation several best
practices for the conduct and
presentation of BCA. In addition, the
EPA would require that a reasoned
explanation be provided for any
departures from best practices in the
BCA, including a discussion of the
likely effect of the departures on the
results of the BCA.
The proposed requirements itemized
in the following subsections are among
the best practices outlined in existing
peer-reviewed OMB and EPA guidance
documents developed in response to
longstanding presidential orders
discussed above: OMB’s Circular A–4
(2003) and its associated guidance
(2010, 2011a, 2011b),20 EPA’s
Guidelines for Preparing Economic
Analyses (2010). These guidance
documents are grounded in the
economics literature pertaining to the
conduct of BCA. Benefit-cost analysis as
a discipline is a branch of applied
microeconomic welfare economics and
is summarized in numerous textbooks
20 Office of Management and Budget, U.S., 2003.
Circular A–4: Regulatory Analysis. Office of
Management and Budget, U.S., 2010. Agency
Checklist: Regulatory Impact Analysis. Office of
Management and Budget, U.S., 2011a. Circular A–
4, ‘‘Regulatory Analysis’’ Frequently Asked
Questions (FAQs). Office of Management and
Budget, U.S., 2011b. Circular A–4, ‘‘Regulatory
Impact Analysis: A Primer’’.
E:\FR\FM\11JNP1.SGM
11JNP1
35618
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 113 / Thursday, June 11, 2020 / Proposed Rules
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with PROPOSALS
such as Boardman et al. (2018), Farrow
(2018), Brent (2006), Mishan and Quah
(2007), and Hanley and Spash (1996).21
This discipline is applied routinely to
environmental economics issues and the
theory of BCA and its application can be
found in standard environmental
economic textbooks such as Phaneuf
and Requate (2016) and Perman et al.
(2012).22 Specific lists of best practices
and guidance for practitioners can also
be found in articles by Robinson and
Hammit (2016), Sunstein (2014), Farrow
(2013), Farrow and Viscusi (2011),
Krutilla (2005), and notably in an article
on the principles and standards by
Nobel laureate Kenneth Arrow and a
number of prominent economists
(Arrow et al., 1996).23
Since best practices for the conduct of
BCA inherently require that the inputs
to analysis reflect the best available
information,24 the EPA is also taking the
opportunity in this proposal to require
that the EPA follow certain best
practices regarding the incorporation of
information as an input to BCA for
significant CAA regulations. In
particular, risk assessments often
provide key inputs to the development
of EPA’s health benefit estimates in a
BCA, and several commenters
recommended that additional
consistency and transparency be
applied in the assessment of risks
leading to the estimation of benefits.
Through this rulemaking, the EPA
proposes requirements to ensure the
21 Farrow, S. ed., 2018. Teaching Benefit-Cost
Analysis: Tools of the Trade. Edward Elgar
Publishing. Brent, R.J. ed., 2004. Applied CostBenefit Analysis. Edward Elgar Publishing. Mishan,
E.J. and Quah, E., 2007. Cost-benefit analysis.
Routledge. Hanley, N. and Spash, C., 1996. Cost
benefit analysis and the environment.
22 Phaneuf, D.J. and Requate, T., 2016. A course
in environmental economics: Theory, policy, and
practice. Cambridge University Press. Perman, R.,
Ma, Y., McGilvray, J. and Common, M., 2003.
Natural resource and environmental economics.
Pearson Education. Krutilla, K., 2005. Using the
Kaldor-Hicks tableau format for cost-benefit
analysis and policy evaluation. Journal of Policy
Analysis and Management: The Journal of the
Association for Public Policy Analysis and
Management, 24(4), pp.864–875.
23 Robinson, L.A. and Hammitt, J.K., 2013. Skills
of the trade: Valuing health risk reductions in
benefit-cost analysis. Journal of Benefit-Cost
Analysis, 4(1), pp.107–130. Sunstein, C.R., 2014.
The real world of cost-benefit analysis: Thirty-six
questions (and almost as many answers). Columbia
Law Review, pp.167–211. Farrow, S., 2013. How
(not) to lie with benefit-cost analysis. The
Economists’ Voice, 10(1), pp.45–50. Farrow, S. and
Viscusi, W.K., 2011. Towards principles and
standards for the benefit-cost analysis of safety.
Journal of Benefit-Cost Analysis, 2(3), pp.1–25.
24 See EPA, Guidelines for Ensuring and
Maximizing the Quality, Objectivity, Utility and
Integrity of Information Disseminated by the
Environmental Protection Agency (https://
www.epa.gov/sites/production/files/2019-08/
documents/epa-info-quality-guidelines_1.pdf).
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:51 Jun 10, 2020
Jkt 250001
consistent and transparent use of risk
assessments in BCA of CAA regulations.
These proposed requirements include
elements that are responsive to
recommendations from the National
Academies of Sciences, Engineering and
Medicine (National Academies) and
EPA’s Science Advisory Board (SAB) to
improve the utility of risk assessment
for use in BCAs for CAA regulations.
This proposal is also consistent with the
2007 OMB and OSTP Updated
Principles for Risk Analysis,25 which
also builds off of the National
Academies and SAB recommendations
as well as EPA’s Risk Characterization
Handbook.26
Key elements of a Benefit-Cost
Analysis. The key elements of a rigorous
regulatory BCA include: (1) A statement
of need; (2) an examination of regulatory
options; and (3) to the extent feasible, an
assessment of all benefits and costs of
these regulatory options relative to the
baseline (no action) scenario.
It will not always be possible to
express in monetary units all of the
important benefits and costs. When it is
not, the most efficient alternative will
not necessarily be the one with the
largest quantified and monetized netbenefit estimate. In such cases, EPA will
exercise its subject matter expertise in
determining how important the nonquantified benefits or costs may be in
the context of the overall analysis. Even
when a benefit or cost cannot be
expressed in monetary units, EPA will
try to measure it in terms of its physical
units. If it is not possible to measure the
physical units, EPA will describe
material benefits or costs qualitatively.
Statement of Need. Each regulatory
BCA should include a statement of need
that provides (1) a clear description of
the problem being addressed, (2) the
reasons for and significance of any
failure of private markets or public
institutions causing this problem, and
(3) the compelling need for federal
government intervention in the market
to correct the problem. This statement
sets the stage for the subsequent
analysis of benefits and costs and allows
one to judge whether the problem is
being adequately addressed by the
policy. Additional discussion of a
thorough regulatory statement of need
can be found in OMB (1993, B.
Introduction, The Need for Federal
Regulatory Action) and EPA (2010,
Chapter 3).
Regulatory Options. The BCA must
analyze the benefits and costs of
25 https://www.whitehouse.gov/sites/
whitehouse.gov/files/omb/memoranda/2007/m0724.pdf.
26 https://www.epa.gov/risk/risk-characterizationhandbook (EPA 100–B–00–002, December 2000).
PO 00000
Frm 00017
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
regulatory options, or other notable
deviations from the proposed or
finalized option. Where there is a
continuum of options (such as options
that vary in stringency), the BCA must
analyze at least three options which
accomplish the stated objectives of the
Clean Air Act (unless the BCA explains
the rationale for analyzing fewer than
three options, as further described
below) and must explain why they were
selected: The proposed or finalized
option; a more stringent option that
achieves additional benefits (and
presumably costs more) beyond those
realized by the proposed or finalized
option; and a less stringent option that
costs less (and presumably generates
fewer benefits) than the proposed or
finalized option. Even when a
continuum of options is not applicable,
an analysis of regulatory options
provides an opportunity to analyze a
variety of parameters including different
compliance dates, enforcement
methods, standards by size or location
of facilities, and regulatory designs (e.g.,
performance vs. technology standards).
If fewer than three options are analyzed,
or if there is a continuum of options and
the options analyzed do not include at
least one more stringent (or otherwise
more costly) and one less stringent (or
otherwise less costly) option than the
proposed or finalized option, then the
BCA must explain why it is not
appropriate to consider more
alternatives. For further discussion, see
OMB Circular A–4, E. Identifying and
Measuring Benefits and Costs, General
Issues, 3. Evaluation of Alternatives.
Baseline. The baseline in a BCA
serves as a basis of comparison with the
regulatory options considered. It is the
best assessment of the way the world
would look absent the regulatory action.
The choice of a baseline requires
consideration of a wide range of
potential factors, including exogenous
changes in the economy that may affect
relevant benefits and costs (e.g., changes
over time in demographics, economic
activity, consumer preferences, and
technology); impacts of regulations that
have been promulgated by the agency or
other government entities; and the
degree of compliance by regulated
entities with other regulations.
Accounting for other existing
regulations in the baseline is especially
important in order to avoid double
counting of the incremental benefits and
costs from other existing regulatory
actions affecting the same
environmental condition (e.g., ambient
air quality). When the EPA determines
that it is appropriate to consider more
than one baseline (e.g., one that
E:\FR\FM\11JNP1.SGM
11JNP1
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 113 / Thursday, June 11, 2020 / Proposed Rules
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with PROPOSALS
accounts for another EPA regulation
being developed at the same time that
would affect the same environmental
condition), the BCA must provide a
reasoned explanation for the baselines
used in sensitivity analyses and must
identify the key uncertainties in the
forecast(s). These proposed
requirements for developing a baseline
are consistent with best practices as
outlined in OMB’s Circular A–4 (1993)
and EPA’s Guidelines (2010).
Measuring Benefits and Costs. A BCA
evaluates the favorable effects of a
policy action and the opportunity costs
associated with the action. It addresses
the question of whether the benefits
from the policy action are sufficient for
those who gain to theoretically
compensate those burdened such that
everyone would be at least as well off
as before the policy. In other words,
many regulations can be thought of as
a requirement to divert resources from
activities with a higher net return in
private markets alone to those with a
higher net return when all impacts are
counted, thus the calculation of net
benefits (benefits minus costs) helps
ascertain the economic efficiency of a
regulation.
In keeping with best practices, the
appropriate measures of benefits and
costs to use in a regulatory BCA are
social benefits and social costs. When
assessing a regulation, the social
benefits are the society-wide positive
changes in well-being, and social costs
are the society-wide opportunities
foregone, or reductions in well-being.
Willingness to pay (WTP) is the correct
measure of these changes in BCA.27
WTP provides a full accounting of an
individual’s preference for an outcome
by identifying what the individual
would give up to attain that outcome.
WTP is measured in monetary terms to
allow a comparison of benefits to costs
in the net benefit calculation. If the BCA
departs from these best practices (e.g.,
where WTP is hard to measure), it must
include a robust explanation for doing
27 Willingness to pay means the largest amount of
money that an individual or group would pay to
receive the benefits (or avoid the damages) resulting
from a policy change, without being made worse
off. The principle of WTP captures the notion of
opportunity cost by measuring what individuals are
willing to forgo to enjoy a particular benefit. In
general, economists tend to view WTP as the most
appropriate measure of opportunity cost, but an
individual’s ‘‘willingness-to-accept’’ (WTA)
compensation for not receiving the improvement
can also provide a valid measure of opportunity
cost. WTP is generally considered to be more
readily measurable. Market prices provide rich data
for estimating benefits and costs based on WTP if
the goods and services affected by the regulation are
traded in well-functioning competitive markets. See
Hanley and Spash (1993), Freeman (2003), Just et
al. (2005), and Appendix A of the Guidelines (2010/
14).
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:51 Jun 10, 2020
Jkt 250001
so. For further discussion, see OMB
Circular A–4, E. Identifying and
Measuring Benefits and Costs, General
Issues, 2. Developing a Baseline and
Guidelines (2010/2014), Chapter 5.
Baseline.
While based on the same underlying
conceptual framework, social benefits
and social costs are often evaluated
separately due to practical
considerations. The social benefits of
reduced pollution are often attributable
to changes in outcomes not exchanged
in markets, such as improvements in
public health or ecosystems. In contrast,
the social costs generally are measured
through changes in outcomes that are
exchanged in markets. As a result,
different techniques are used to estimate
social benefits and social costs however,
in both cases the goal is to estimate
measures of WTP to provide
consistency.
Methods for Estimating Benefits and
Costs. Although the most appropriate
methods for estimating social costs and
social benefits can often be regulationspecific, there are best practices for
selecting these methods. The EPA
proposes that all BCAs will rely on such
best practices and will provide reasoned
explanations for methods selected.
These best practices include the use of
a framework that is appropriate for the
characteristics of the regulation being
evaluated. As discussed in OMB
Circular A–4, a good regulatory analysis
cannot be developed according to a
formula. Conducting high-quality
analysis requires competent
professional judgment. Different
regulations may call for different
emphases in the analysis, depending on
the nature and complexity of the
regulatory issues and the sensitivity of
the benefit and cost estimates to the key
assumptions. For example, the extent to
which compliance cost is a sufficient
measure of social costs will depend on
whether a regulation is expected to
result in changes in prices and
quantities within and across markets.
Other considerations when selecting an
estimation method include the ability of
an estimation approach to capture
certain types of costs, to adequately
reflect the geographic and sectoral detail
and scope of the rule, and to reflect how
costs may change over time, among
other considerations.
During the estimation process,
analysts must consider how social cost
and benefit endpoints may be affected
by behaviors in the baseline and
potential behavioral changes from the
policy. For example, three broad
frameworks for estimating social cost—
compliance cost, partial equilibrium,
and general equilibrium—offer different
PO 00000
Frm 00018
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
35619
scopes in terms of the degree to which
behavioral response and other market
imperfections are included. In general,
analysts can improve the accuracy of
cost estimates by reducing known biases
due to the omission of potentially
important behavioral responses or
missing opportunity costs. However,
adopting more complex approaches can
reduce the precision of estimates due to
data and modeling limitations. A
compliance cost approach typically
identifies the private expenditures
associated with compliance in the
regulated sector(s). Compliance cost
estimates typically exclude behavioral
responses outside of the choice of
compliance activity and may, therefore,
not capture some opportunity costs
associated with regulations. However,
with adequate data, this approach can
generate highly detailed and relatively
precise information on compliance
options and costs, reflecting the
heterogeneity of regulated entities. This
can provide a reasonable estimate of the
social cost of a regulation when changes
in the regulated sector’s outputs and
input mix are expected to be minimal
and no large market effects are
anticipated. A partial equilibrium
analysis captures supply and demand
responses in the regulated sector due to
compliance activities and may,
therefore, provide a more complete
estimate of compliance costs in addition
to any lost profits and consumer welfare
due to reductions in output. In other
words, behavioral responses can have
important impacts on both the size and
distribution of benefits and costs, and
therefore can provide a fuller picture of
the social impact of a particular
regulation. Partial equilibrium analyses
may be extended to consider a small
number of related sectors in addition to
those directly regulated (e.g., upstream
markets that supply intermediate goods
to the regulated sector, or markets for
substitute or complementary products).
A partial equilibrium approach is
preferred for estimating social cost
when the regulation will result in
appreciable behavioral change, but the
effects will be confined primarily to a
single market or a small number of
markets. When broader economy-wide
impacts are expected as a result of the
regulation, a partial equilibrium
approach will miss these effects. In this
case, a general equilibrium approach
may be more appropriate to more
adequately estimate social cost.
A general equilibrium approach,
which captures linkages between
markets across the entire economy, is
most likely to add value when both
relevant relationships among sectors
E:\FR\FM\11JNP1.SGM
11JNP1
35620
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 113 / Thursday, June 11, 2020 / Proposed Rules
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with PROPOSALS
and pre-existing market distortions are
expected to be significant. Market
distortions are factors such as preexisting taxes, externalities, regulations,
or imperfectly competitive markets that
move consumers or firms away from
what would occur in the absence of
such distortions. For example, when an
environmental regulation affects the real
wage such that individuals opt to work
fewer hours, it can exacerbate preexisting inefficiencies in the labor
market due to taxes, regulatory barriers,
or other market imperfections. This
represents a welfare cost not captured
by compliance cost estimates. The
impacts of a regulation also may interact
with pre-existing distortions in other
markets, which may cause additional
impacts on welfare either positively or
negatively. In cases such as these, a
general equilibrium approach may be
capable of identifying how the costs of
complying with a regulation flow
through the economy, such as through
changes in substitution among factors of
production, trade patterns, and demand
for goods and services. These effects are
partially or wholly missed by
compliance cost and partial equilibrium
approaches. For further discussion, see
Guidelines (2010/2014), Chapter 8,
Analyzing Costs, 8.1. The Economics of
Social Cost.
The estimated social benefits reported
in a BCA should link regulatory
requirements to the value that
individuals place on the beneficial
outcomes,28 or benefit endpoints, that
can be meaningfully expected as a result
of those requirements. Benefits
assessment is, therefore, typically a
multi-step process. The starting point is
identifying the changes in
environmental contaminants or stressors
that are likely to result from policy
options relative to the baseline. These
changes are often characterized through
air quality modeling. The next step is to
identify the benefit endpoints that may
be affected by changes in environmental
quality, such as human health
improvements, ecological
improvements, aesthetic improvements,
and reduced materials damages. The
EPA recognizes that the strength of
scientific evidence for different health
or environmental endpoints varies, and
28 As a practical matter, the value of any adverse
public health or welfare outcomes (sometimes
referred to as ‘‘disbenefits’’) resulting from the
regulatory requirements are usually also included
on the benefits side of the ledger in regulatory
BCAs, although it is theoretically appropriate to
include them on the cost side. Such adverse
outcomes could include adverse economic, health,
safety, or environmental consequences that occur
due to a rule (e.g., adverse safety impacts from
vehicle emission standards) and are not already
accounted for in the direct cost of the rule.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:51 Jun 10, 2020
Jkt 250001
that strength of scientific evidence
should be strongest when the benefits
are estimated. As further discussed in
OMB’s M 19–15, this concept is referred
to as ‘‘fitness for purpose,’’ whereby
information anticipated to have a higher
impact must be held to higher standards
of quality.29
The EPA proposes to select the
endpoints for which the scientific
evidence indicates there is (a) a clear
causal or likely causal relationship
between pollutant exposure and effect,
and subsequently, (b) an anticipated
change in that effect in response to
changes in environmental quality or
exposures is expected as a result of the
regulation under analysis. EPA takes
comment on an alternative, approach
that would select all endpoints for
which there is a positive WTP
conditional on the available scientific
literature.
Once benefit endpoints are identified,
decisions must be made about whether
and how to quantify changes in each
endpoint. From among the endpoints
identified above, the EPA proposes to
quantify effects for endpoints which
scientific evidence is robust enough to
support such quantification. If the
Agency determines that some benefits
should be discussed only qualitatively,
for example, due to limited scientific
evidence or limited resources for
developing concentration response
functions, the Agency must provide a
reasoned explanation for that decision.
Additional information on choosing and
quantifying health endpoints is
described further below.
Quantification is then followed by
valuation of these endpoints when data
and methods allow. There are welldefined economic principles and wellestablished economic methods for
valuation as detailed in OMB and
Agency guidance, including Circular A–
4 and the EPA Guidelines for Preparing
Economic Analyses. Finally, the valued
endpoints should be aggregated to the
extent possible and supported by
scientific and economic practice to
provide the basis for characterizing the
benefits of each policy option.
In some instances, it may be possible
to value bundles of attributes or
endpoints using reduced-form
techniques, such as the hedonic
property method. Care and professional
29 OMB’s M–19–15 refers back to OMB’s 2002
Guidelines, which characterize a subset of agency
information as ‘‘influential scientific, financial, or
statistical information’’ that is held to higher
quality standards. This is scientific, financial, or
statistical information that ‘‘the agency can
reasonably determine . . . will have or does have
a clear and substantial impact on important public
policies or important private sector decisions.’’
PO 00000
Frm 00019
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
judgment are necessary in determining
the appropriateness of bundling of
several endpoints versus modeling
separate endpoints. Even if bundling is
thought to be appropriate, it can be
useful to think through the multi-step
process above conceptually to: (a)
Assess whether there are benefit
endpoints not reflected in the reduced
form valuation estimate that should be
included through additional analysis, or
(b) compare the magnitudes of multistep and reduced-form, revealedpreference benefits estimates so that
each can provide a check on the
reliability of the other.
In summary, the EPA proposes that, to
the extent supported by the scientific
criteria, as discussed above, as well as
practicable in a given rulemaking, (1)
BCAs will quantify all benefits; (2)
BCAs will monetize all the benefits by
following well-defined economic
principles using well-established
economic methods; and (3) BCAs will
qualitatively characterize benefits that
cannot be quantified or monetized. In
addition, the EPA proposes that the
Agency must explain any departure
from the best practices for the BCA
described in Circular A–4; this includes
discussing the likely effect of the
departures on the size of the benefits
estimate. More discussion of these best
practices and estimation methods is
provided in Circular A–4 and EPA’s
Guidelines for Preparing Economic
Analyses, and the literature cited
therein.
Quantifying Health Endpoints in a
BCA: Decisions about whether and
which changes in the health endpoints
should be quantified should be
informed by the Agency’s evaluation of
the relevant scientific literature
establishing a link between chemical
exposure and health endpoint and the
nature of the concentration-response
function (i.e., the amount of change in
the frequency or severity of the health
endpoint expected as the distribution of
air quality changes.) In its evaluation,
the Agency should explicitly state when
scientific judgments or assumptions
were used and their effect on the
concentration-response function, if
known. The Agency would select among
concentration-response relationships
from studies that satisfied the following
minimum standards: (1) The study was
externally and independently peerreviewed consistent with Federal
guidance; (2) the pollutant analyzed in
the study matches the pollutant of
interest in the regulation; (3)
concentration-response functions must
be parameterized from scientifically
robust studies; and (4) when an
epidemiological study is used, further
E:\FR\FM\11JNP1.SGM
11JNP1
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with PROPOSALS
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 113 / Thursday, June 11, 2020 / Proposed Rules
criteria include: (a) It must assess the
influence of confounders; (b) the study
location must be appropriately matched
to the analysis; and (c) the study
population characteristics must be
sufficiently similar to those of the
analysis. When multiple studies satisfy
these criteria, the EPA would
characterize multiple concentrationresponse functions reflecting the full set
of studies as a means of providing a
broader representation of the effects
estimate, including high quality studies
that do not find a significant
concentration-response relationship.
When selecting multiple
concentration-response functions, the
Agency would quantify risks using
separate concentration-response
relationship and, if appropriate, pool, or
combine, the results (e.g. in a metaanalysis) as means of providing a
broader representation of the effects
estimate. EPA proposes to require that
decisions about the choice of the
number of alternative concentrationresponse functions quantified for each
endpoint be based on the extent to
which it is technically feasible to
quantify alternative concentrationresponse relationships given the
available data and resources. Decisions
should also consider the sensitivity of
net benefits to the choice of
concentration-response function. EPA
proposes to present results in a manner
that promotes transparency in the
assessment process by selecting and
clearly identifying concentrationresponse functions with the strongest
scientific evidence, as well as evidence
necessary to demonstrate the sensitivity
of the choice of the concentrationresponse function on the magnitude and
the uncertainty associated with air
pollution-attributable effects.
Once the Agency has identified the
concentration-response functions to be
used for quantifying the selected health
endpoints, the Agency proposes that the
BCA, or related technical support
document, must characterize:
• The variability in the concentrationresponse functions across studies and
models, including plausible
alternatives;
• the assumptions, defaults, and
uncertainties, their rationale, and their
influence on the resulting estimates;
• the extent to which scientific
literature suggests that the nature of the
effect may vary across demographic or
health characteristics;
• the potential variability of the
concentration-response function over
the range in concentrations of interest
for the given policy;
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:51 Jun 10, 2020
Jkt 250001
• the influence of potential
confounders on the reported risk
coefficient;
• the likelihood that the parameters
of the concentration-response differ
based on geographic location; and
• attributes that affect the suitability
of the study or model for informing a
risk assessment, including the age of the
air quality data, and the generalizability
of the study population.
In cases where existing Agency
documents (e.g., an Integrated Science
Assessment for criteria pollutants)
provide the causal analysis,
concentration-response analysis, or the
factors indicated above to be included
in the BCA, the BCA may reference this
synthesis. Evidence from epidemiologic,
experimental, and controlled human
exposure studies may suggest that
certain demographic subgroups are
subject to risks that differ from the
general population; in these instances, it
may be appropriate to select
concentration-response relationships
that quantify risks among these specific
subgroups.
BCA requires a comparison of
expected costs and expected benefits, so
BCA for CAA regulations must include
the determination of expected benefits.
When feasible, a probability distribution
of risk is appropriate to use when
determining the expected benefits for
CAA regulations. When it is infeasible
to estimate a probability distribution,
the EPA proposes that measures of the
central tendency of risk be used. Upperbound risk estimates must not be used
unless they are presented in conjunction
with lower bound and central tendency
estimates.
Uncertainty Analysis. For various
reasons, including the reason that the
future is unpredictable, the benefits and
costs of future regulatory options are not
known with certainty. BCAs should
identify uncertainties underlying the
estimation of both benefits and costs
and, to the extent feasible,
quantitatively analyze those that are
most influential. Specifically, the EPA
must characterize, preferably
quantitatively, sources of uncertainty in
the assessment of costs, changes in air
quality, assessment of likely changes in
health and welfare endpoints, and the
valuation of those changes. The EPA
must also present benefit and cost
estimates in ways that convey their
uncertainty. The BCA must include a
reasoned explanation for the scope of
the uncertainty analysis and must
specify specific quantitative or
qualitative methods chosen to analyze
uncertainties. Quantitative uncertainty
analyses may consider both statistical
and model uncertainty where the data
PO 00000
Frm 00020
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
35621
are sufficient to do so. Furthermore,
where data are sufficient to do so, the
BCA must consider sources of
uncertainty independently as well as
jointly. The BCA should also discuss the
extent to which qualitatively assessed
costs or benefits are characterized by
uncertainty.
Where probability distributions for
relevant input assumptions are
available, characterize significant
sources of uncertainty in the
assessment, and can be feasibly and
credibly combined, the EPA proposes
that BCAs characterize how the
probability distributions of the relevant
input assumption uncertainty would
impact the resulting distribution of
benefit and cost estimates. The EPA
should report probability distributions
for each health benefit whenever
feasible. In addition to characterizing
these distributions of outcomes, it is
useful to emphasize summary statistics
or figures that can be readily understood
and compared to achieve the broadest
public understanding of the findings. If
this proposed rulemaking is adopted,
there will be instances when calculating
expected values is not practicable due to
data or other limitations. In such
instances, the EPA would strive to
present a plausible range of benefits and
costs. Additional discussion of these
best practices related to uncertainty
analysis is provided in OMB’s Circular
A–4, Treatment of Uncertainty, and
throughout EPA’s Guidelines for
Preparing Economic Analyses
Guidelines.
Principle of Transparency. The EPA
proposes that BCA of significant CAA
regulations include, at a minimum, a
detailed and clear explanation of:
• The overall results of the BCA. The
EPA proposes that the benefits, costs,
and net benefits of each regulatory
option evaluated in the BCA be
presented in a manner designed to be
objective, comprehensive, and easily
understood by the public.
• How the benefits and costs were
estimated, including the assumptions
made for the analysis. BCAs must
include a clear explanation of the
models, data, and assumptions used to
estimate benefits and costs, and the
evaluation and selection process for
these analytical decisions. This
explanation would also include an
explanation of procedures used to select
among input parameters for the benefit
and cost models. Such an explanation
could include methods used to quantify
risk and to model the fate and transport
of pollutants.
• All non-monetized and nonquantified benefits and costs of the
action. BCAs must provide available
E:\FR\FM\11JNP1.SGM
11JNP1
35622
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 113 / Thursday, June 11, 2020 / Proposed Rules
evidence on all non-monetized and nonquantified benefits and costs, including
why they are not being monetized or
quantified and what the potential
impact of those benefits and costs might
be on the overall results of the BCA.
• The primary sources and potential
effects of uncertainty. The BCA must
present the results of the assessment of
the sources of uncertainty that are likely
to have a substantial effect on the
results. Any data and models used to
analyze uncertainty must be fully
identified, and the quality of the
available data must be discussed.
Finally, to the extent permitted by
law, the EPA proposes to make the
information (including data and models)
that was used in the development of the
BCA publicly available. If the data and
models are proprietary, the EPA
proposes to make the underlying inputs
and assumptions used, primary
equations, and methodologies available
to the extent permitted by law, while
continuing to protect information
claimed as confidential business
information (CBI), personally
identifiable information (PII), and other
privileged, non-exempt information.
Additional discussion of these best
practices related to transparency is
provided in OMB’s Circular A–4,
Transparency and Reproducibility of
Results, and throughout EPA’s
Guidelines (2010).
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with PROPOSALS
C. Requirement for Additional
Presentations of BCA Results in
Rulemakings
One theme raised by many
commenters on the ANPRM was that the
EPA does not clearly distinguish benefit
categories in its regulatory documents.
These commenters stated that EPA’s
BCAs generally present benefits as an
aggregate total, and that insufficient
effort is made to clearly distinguish
between the public health and welfare
benefits attributable to the specific
pollution reductions or other
environmental quality goals that are
targeted by the specific statutory
provision or provisions that authorize
the regulation, and other welfare effects
of the regulation that are not the
primary objective of the statutory
provision or provisions. For example,
some commenters pointed to reports
that show that for regulations for which
a BCA is available, the majority of the
monetized benefits for CAA regulations
were attributable to reductions in fine
particulate matter (PM2.5) even though
the regulation did not target PM2.5. This
issue did not arise with respect to costs
in the public comments received on the
ANPRM.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:51 Jun 10, 2020
Jkt 250001
While BCA requires a comparison of
total social benefits and total social
costs, commenters state that this
comparison does not transparently
communicate and may also create
public confusion about the nature and
scope of the statutory authority that
provides the basis for the regulation, if
a disproportionate share of social
benefits arise from changes in
environmental and other outcomes
unrelated or secondary to the statutory
objective of the regulation. While the
Agency did not receive public
comments on the presentation of costs,
this principle of transparency would
also apply to considerations of cost as
contemplated by the statute when in
pursuit those environmental benefits.
Following the principle of
transparency, the EPA agrees with
commenters that when presenting the
results of a BCA, it is important to
clearly distinguish between the social
benefits attributable to the specific
pollution reductions or other
environmental quality goals that are
targeted by the statutory provisions that
give rise to the regulation, and other
welfare effects. The disaggregation of
welfare effects will be important to
ensure that the BCA may provide, to the
maximum extent feasible, transparency
in decision making. These other welfare
effects could include both favorable and
adverse impacts on societal welfare.
Analogous to how a regulation’s
interactions with existing imperfections
or distortions in other markets (e.g., due
to pre-existing taxes) could lead to
additional social costs, a regulation
could ameliorate or exacerbate other
pre-existing externalities. For example,
more stringent vehicle emissions
standards could affect upstream refinery
emissions or reduce the marginal cost of
driving due to greater fuel efficiency
and could lead to an increase in vehicle
miles traveled that affects road safety,
congestion, and other transport-related
externalities.
Other welfare effects could also occur
as a direct or indirect result of the
compliance approaches used by
regulated entities. For example, changes
in other environmental contaminants
may arise from the regulated sources.
Likewise, the use of an abatement
technology that reduces the emissions of
HAPs into one medium (e.g., air) may
change the emissions of another
pollutant into the same medium (e.g.,
coming out of the same smokestack) or
cause changes in emissions of pollutants
into another medium (e.g., water) by the
regulated sources. Changes in other
environmental contaminants may also
occur as a result of market interactions
induced by the regulation. For example,
PO 00000
Frm 00021
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
a regulation may cause consumers or
firms to substitute away from one
commodity towards another, whose
increased production may be associated
with changes in various environmental
contaminants or other externalities.
The welfare effects associated with
these changes should be accounted for
in a BCA to the extent feasible, as it is
the total willingness to pay for all
changes induced by a regulation that
determines their relative importance in
evaluating economic efficiency.
Disaggregating benefits into those
targeted and ancillary to the statutory
objective of the regulation may cause
the EPA to explore whether there may
be more efficient, lawful and defensible,
or otherwise appropriate ways of
obtaining ancillary benefits, as they may
be the primary target of an alternative
regulation that may more efficiently
address such pollutants, through a more
flexible regulatory mechanism, better
geographic focus, or other factors. This
may be relevant when certain benefits
are the result of changes in pollutants
that the EPA regulates under a different
section of the CAA or under another
statute.
Proposed Requirements: EPA
proposes to codify into regulation two
presentational requirements for the
preamble of all future significant CAA
regulations. First, in order to ensure
standardized presentation of the
summary of the BCA results consistent
with E.O. 12866 in CAA rulemakings,
the EPA proposes to codify into
regulation the requirement to present a
summary in the preamble of the overall
BCA results, including total costs,
benefits, and net benefits. Second, to
enhance transparency about the extent
to which a rule is achieving its statutory
objectives, the EPA proposes, in
addition to a clear reporting of the
overall results of the BCA, an additional
presentation in the preamble of the
public health and welfare benefits that
pertain to the specific objective (or
objectives, as the case may be) of the
CAA provision or provisions under
which the rule is promulgated. This
second presentation would include a
listing of the benefit categories arising
from the environmental improvement
that is targeted by the relevant statutory
provision, or provisions and would
report the monetized value to society of
these benefits. If these benefit categories
cannot be monetized, the EPA is
proposing that the Agency must report
the quantified estimates of these
benefits to the extent practicable and
must provide a qualitative
characterization if they cannot be
quantified. Similarly, if the statute
directs or allows the Agency to consider
E:\FR\FM\11JNP1.SGM
11JNP1
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 113 / Thursday, June 11, 2020 / Proposed Rules
V. Additional Considerations and
Requests for Comment
cost, it may be appropriate, depending
on the statutory provision at issue, to
consider whether the benefits of a
regulation justify the costs in deciding
whether or how to regulate.
In this proposal, the EPA solicits
comment on how the Agency could take
into consideration the results of a BCA
in future rulemakings under specific
provisions of the CAA. The EPA also
solicits comment on approaches for how
the results of the BCA could be weighed
in future CAA regulatory decisions. For
example, the EPA solicits comment on
whether and under what circumstances
the EPA could or should determine that
a future significant CAA regulation be
promulgated only when the benefits of
the intended action justify its costs. The
EPA also solicits comment on whether
and under what circumstances the EPA
could determine that a future significant
CAA regulation be promulgated only
when monetized benefits exceed the
costs of the action.
A. Specifying How BCA Results Should
Inform Regulatory Decisions
The EPA is proposing that the Agency
undertake a BCA for significant
regulations but is not proposing to
specify how or whether the results of
the BCA should inform significant CAA
regulatory decisions. For example, the
EPA is not proposing to mandate that a
significant CAA regulation be
promulgated only when the benefits of
the intended action justify its costs.
Such a mandate would not be
appropriate, for example, for regulations
promulgated under provisions of the
CAA that have been read by the courts
to prohibit the consideration of costs in
decision-making. For example, ‘‘[t]he
text of § 109(b), interpreted in its
statutory and historical context and
with appreciation for its importance to
the CAA as a whole, unambiguously
bars cost considerations from the
NAAQS-setting process.’’ Am. Trucking
Ass’ns, 531 U.S. at 471. Thus, such a
mandate would be improper for the
NAAQS-setting process. There are other
CAA provisions, however, that
explicitly require the EPA to take costs
into consideration in deciding how or
whether to regulate. In addition, several
provisions do not explicitly use the
word ‘‘cost’’ but use terminology that
implicitly requires or permits cost
consideration. For example, terms such
as ‘‘reasonable,’’ ‘‘appropriate,’’
‘‘necessary,’’ or ‘‘feasible’’ have been
interpreted as allowing for or even
requiring the consideration of cost in
decision making. Accordingly, when
regulating pursuant to a CAA provision
that either explicitly or implicitly
requires or permits consideration of
B. Other Areas of Solicitation for Public
Comment
Applicability. EPA is requesting
comment on whether this rulemaking
should apply only to the subset of CAA
significant regulations that are
determined to be economically
significant, which the EPA could define,
consistent with E.O. 12866 Section
3(f)(1) and OMB Circular A–4, as those
that are likely to have an effect on the
economy (benefits, costs or transfers) of
$100 million or more in any one year
(that is, a consecutive twelve-month
period) or adversely affect in a material
way the economy, a sector of the
economy, productivity, competition,
jobs, the environment, public health or
safety, or State, local, or tribal
governments or communities. These
economically significant regulations are
the same set of regulations for which
E.O. 12866 requires the preparation of a
BCA. The EPA also requests comment
on whether the threshold of $100
million in benefits and/or costs in any
given year should be adjusted for
inflation going forward, and, if so,
whether such adjustments should be
made assuming a base year of 1995 (as
is done with the $100 million
expenditure threshold set forth in the
Unfunded Mandates Reform Act).The
EPA is requesting comment on whether
certain elements of the proposed action
should consider resource constraints
when being implemented for CAA
significant regulations, under the
reasonable proposition embedded in
E.O. 12866 that the intensity of the
resources dedicated to an analysis
should be coordinated and consistent
with the level of impact of a decision.
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with PROPOSALS
costs, the EPA proposes to also provide
a disaggregation of all relevant cost
categories to the extent feasible in this
section. This proposed requirement
would serve as supplement to the BCA
that is developed and presented
according to best practices as outlined
in Section IV.B of this preamble. It does
not replace or change any part of the
RIA or the section of the preamble that
summarizes the BCA results consistent
with E.O. 12866. As discussed in
Section V of this preamble, the EPA
requests comment on alternative ways
of increasing transparency about the
extent to which a rule is achieving its
statutory environmental objective.
Finally, the EPA proposes that the
presentational requirements described
above be provided in the same section
of the preamble of future CAA
significant rulemakings.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:51 Jun 10, 2020
Jkt 250001
PO 00000
Frm 00022
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
35623
Best Practices for the Development of
BCA. The EPA is requesting comment
whether it is appropriate to codify best
practices for the development of BCA in
this rulemaking and, if so, whether
specific additional best practices should
also be so codified. For example, the
EPA solicits comment on whether this
rulemaking should specify best
practices related to assumptions about
technological change and/or learning
effects in BCA. The EPA further solicits
comment as to whether any additional
proposed requirements for BCAs would
improve BCA consistency. EPA solicits
comments as to whether non-domestic
benefits and costs of regulations, when
examined, should be reported separately
from domestic benefits and costs of such
regulations, just as this proposed
rulemaking would provide for a separate
presentation of benefits limited to those
targeted by the relevant statutory
provision or provisions.
The EPA is requesting comment as to
whether requirements related to risk
assessments used in BCAs should be
applied more broadly than as described
in the proposed rulemaking and, in
particular, whether such requirements
should apply to all risk assessments
used in CAA significant rulemakings.
For example, should EPA codify into
regulation the proposed selection
criteria for selecting among studies
characterizing concentration-response
relationships and the proposed
requirement for synthesizing evidence
across the literature? The EPA also
solicits comment on whether to impose
additional requirements for risk
assessments. For example, should the
EPA impose requirements for best
practices related to any weight-ofevidence (WOE) frameworks that the
Agency uses in the developments of
CAA significant rulemakings? Should
EPA impose additional requirements to
ensure consistency and transparency in
the assessment of bias and uncertainty
in risk analyses (e.g., requirements
relating to the use of quantitative bias
analysis, or requirements intended for
consistency purposes such as
requirements relating to the use of
probabilistic risk analysis for reducing
uncertainty in risk analysis)? The EPA
also solicits comments on whether
additional requirements within the
study selection criteria are necessary to
ensure a high-quality and appropriately
reliable characterization of air quality
and risk.
Additional Presentational
Requirements to Increase Transparency.
EPA requests comment on alternative
approaches to increasing transparency
about the extent to which a rule is
achieving its statutory objectives. In
E:\FR\FM\11JNP1.SGM
11JNP1
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with PROPOSALS
35624
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 113 / Thursday, June 11, 2020 / Proposed Rules
particular, EPA solicits comment on
whether, instead of, or in addition to,
the presentational requirements
proposed in Section IV.C of this
preamble, the EPA should require a
detailed disaggregation of both benefit
and cost categories within the table that
summarizes the overall results of the
BCA in the preamble of future
significant CAA rulemakings. The goal
of this disaggregation would be to
clarify what public health and welfare
benefits pertain to the specific statutory
objective, or objectives, of the CAA
provision, or provisions, under which
the rule is promulgated, but would
allow the reader to see this information
in the same location as the estimates of
all the other welfare effects, both
positive and negative, resulting from the
regulation. In addition, the EPA solicits
comment on whether the EPA should
require a separate presentation of all
factors (e.g., particular benefit or cost
categories, or other impacts) that are
specifically listed as factors that the
Administrator must consider in making
a regulatory decision pursuant to the
statutory provision(s) under which the
regulation is being promulgated. This
presentation would include a
presentation of quantitative results for
those factors that have been
quantitatively assessed, and a
qualitative discussion of any factors that
were not quantified.
Retrospective Analysis. EPA requests
comment on whether EPA should
include a requirement for conducting
retrospective analysis of significant
CAA rulemakings. As discussed in the
ANPRM, many previous administrations
have periodically undertaken programs
of retrospective review or issued
executive orders urging agencies to
reassess existing regulations and to
eliminate, modify, or strengthen those
regulations that have become outmoded
in light of changed circumstances. But
for the most part retrospective review
has not become institutionalized
practice as has prospective review (such
as ex ante benefit-cost analysis
conducted under Executive Order
12866) within EPA. The EPA received
many comment letters on the ANPRM
voicing support for increased
retrospective review of Agency rules or
programs to be able to evaluate the
effectiveness of regulations and to
design future improvements to increase
efficiency. In this NPRM the EPA
requests more specific comments on this
issue. In particular, what form should a
requirement take in the case of CAA
regulations? For example, should the
requirement pertain to analysis of an
individual rule or a review of the
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:51 Jun 10, 2020
Jkt 250001
cumulative burden of a set of rules
regulating the same or related entities?
Should it be applicable to all parts of
CAA or just some provisions? What are
the advantages and disadvantages of
such a requirement? How can the
Agency overcome the challenges
conducting retrospective analysis in
cases where the EPA’s ability to collect
information about the costs of
compliance is limited or otherwise
influenced by other statutes?
Sequence of Rules in Benefit-Cost
Analysis. EPA seeks comment on how
sequencing of rules might affect the
estimation of benefits and costs.
Definitions. The EPA is requesting
comment on whether there are
additional terms that it should define to
increase consistency and transparency
in the development of BCA to support
CAA rulemaking actions.
Making Information Public. The EPA
requests comments as to whether the
proposed criteria regarding data,
assumptions, and study selection reflect
the Agency’s commitment to be
consistent and transparent. The EPA
solicits comment on whether this rule
should allow the Agency to use models
offered by a third party only where the
third party makes its models and
assumptions publicly available (or
allows the EPA to do so) to the extent
permitted by law.
VI. References
The following is a listing of the
documents that are specifically
referenced in this document. The docket
includes these documents and other
information considered by the EPA,
including documents referenced within
the documents that are included in the
docket, even if a referenced document is
not physically located in the docket. For
assistance in locating these other
documents, please consult the person
listed under the FOR FURTHER
INFORMATION CONTACT section above.
1. U.S. EPA (U.S. Environmental Protection
Agency). Increasing Consistency and
Transparency in Considering Costs and
Benefits in the Rulemaking Process;
Advance notice of proposed rulemaking.
(83 FR 27524, June 13, 2018).
2. OMB (Office of Management and Budget).
(1996). Economic Analysis of Federal
Regulations Under Executive Order
12866.
3. OMB (Office of Management and Budget).
(2003). Circular A–4, ‘‘Regulatory
Analysis.’’
4. U.S. EPA (U.S. Environmental Protection
Agency). (2010). Guidelines for
Preparing Economic Analyses.
5. Arrow, K., M. Cropper, G. Eads, R. Hahn,
L. Lave, R. Noll, P. Portney, M. Russell,
R. Schmalensee, V. Smith, and R.
Stavins. 1996a. Benefit-Cost Analysis in
PO 00000
Frm 00023
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
Environmental, Health, and Safety
Regulation: A Statement of Principles.
Washington, DC: American Enterprise
Institute, The Annapolis Center, and
Resources for the Future.
6. Arrow et al. 1996b. Is There a Role for
Benefit-Cost Analysis in Environmental,
Health, and Safety Regulation? Science
272: 221–222.
VII. Statutory and Executive Order
Reviews
Additional information about these
statutes and Executive Orders can be
found at https://www.epa.gov/lawsregulations/laws-and-executive-orders.
A. Executive Order 12866: Regulatory
Planning and Review and Executive
Order 13563: Improving Regulation and
Regulatory Review
This proposed action is a significant
regulatory action that was submitted to
the OMB for review. Any changes made
in response to OMB recommendations
have been documented in the docket.
The EPA does not anticipate that this
rulemaking will have an economic
impact on regulated entities. This is a
rule of agency procedure and practice.
B. Executive Order 13771: Reducing
Regulations and Controlling Regulatory
Costs
This proposed action is not expected
to be an Executive Order 13771
regulatory action because it relates to
‘‘agency organization, management or
personnel.’’
C. Paperwork Reduction Act (PRA)
This proposed action does not contain
any information collection activities and
therefore does not impose an
information collection burden under the
PRA.
D. Regulatory Flexibility Act (RFA)
I certify that this proposed action
would not have a significant economic
impact on a substantial number of small
entities under the RFA. This action
would not impose any requirements on
small entities. This action would not
regulate any entity outside the federal
government.
E. Unfunded Mandates Reform Act
(UMRA)
This proposed action does not contain
any unfunded mandate as described in
UMRA, 2 U.S.C. 1531–1538, and does
not significantly or uniquely affect small
governments. The action proposed
would impose no enforceable duty on
any state, local or tribal governments or
the private sector.
F. Executive Order 13132: Federalism
This proposed action does not have
federalism implications. It would not
E:\FR\FM\11JNP1.SGM
11JNP1
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 113 / Thursday, June 11, 2020 / Proposed Rules
have substantial direct effects on the
states, on the relationship between the
national government and the states, or
on the distribution of power and
responsibilities among the various
levels of government.
G. Executive Order 13175: Consultation
and Coordination With Indian Tribal
Governments
This proposed action does not have
tribal implications as specified in
Executive Order 13175. Thus, Executive
Order 13175 does not apply to this
action.
H. Executive Order 13045: Protection of
Children From Environmental Health
Risks and Safety Risks
The EPA interprets Executive Order
13045 as applying only to those
regulatory actions that concern
environmental health or safety risks that
the EPA has reason to believe may
disproportionately affect children, per
the definition of ‘‘covered regulatory
action’’ in section 2–202 of the
Executive Order. This proposed action
is not subject to Executive Order 13045
because it does not concern an
environmental health risk or safety risk.
I. Executive Order 13211: Actions
Concerning Regulations That
Significantly Affect Energy Supply,
Distribution or Use
This proposed action is not a
‘‘significant energy action’’ because it is
not likely to have a significant adverse
effect on the supply, distribution or use
of energy.
J. National Technology Transfer and
Advancement Act (NTTAA)
This rulemaking does not involve
technical standards.
K. Executive Order 12898: Federal
Actions To Address Environmental
Justice in Minority Populations and
Low-Income Populations
The EPA believes that this proposed
action is not subject to Executive Order
12898 (59 FR 7629, February 16, 1994)
because it does not establish an
environmental health or safety standard.
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with PROPOSALS
List of Subjects in 40 CFR Part 83
Environmental protection,
Administrative practice and procedure,
Reporting and recordkeeping
requirements.
Andrew Wheeler,
Administrator.
For the reasons set forth in the
preamble, EPA is proposing to add 40
CFR part 83 as follows:
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:51 Jun 10, 2020
Jkt 250001
PART 83—INCREASING
CONSISTENCY AND TRANSPARENCY
IN CONSIDERING BENEFITS AND
COSTS IN CLEAN AIR ACT
RULEMAKING PROCESS
Sec.
83.1
83.2
What definitions apply to this subpart?
How do the provisions of this subpart
apply?
83.3 What requirements apply to EPA’s
preparations of Benefit-Cost Analyses
(BCAs) under the Clean Air Act?
83.4 What additional requirements apply to
EPA’s presentation of BCA results for all
significant rules promulgated under the
Clean Air Act?
Authority: 42 U.S.C. 7601(a)(1)
Subpart A—Analysis of Air
Regulations
§ 83.1 What definitions apply to this
subpart?
Baseline means the best assessment of
the way the world would look absent
the proposed or finalized action.
Benefit-cost analysis (BCA) means an
evaluation of the favorable effects of a
policy action and the opportunity costs,
associated with the action. It addresses
the question whether the benefits for
those who gain from the action are
sufficient to, in principle, compensate
those burdened such that everyone
would be at least as well off as before
the policy. The calculation of net
benefits (benefits minus costs) helps
ascertain the economic efficiency of a
regulation.
Compliance cost means the private
cost that a regulated entity incurs to
comply with a regulation (e.g.,
installation and operation of pollution
abatement equipment).
Data means the set of recorded factual
material commonly accepted in the
scientific community as necessary to
validate research findings in which
obvious errors, such as keystroke or
coding errors, have been removed and
that is capable of being analyzed by
either the original researcher or an
independent party.
Expected value is a measure of the
central tendency of a set of data. It is
usually the average or mean of the data.
For a variable with a discrete number of
outcomes, the expected value is
calculated by multiplying each of the
possible outcomes by the likelihood that
each outcome will occur and then
summing all of those values.
Model means a simplification of
reality that is constructed to gain
insights into select attributes of a
physical, biological, economic, or social
system. A formal representation of the
behavior of system processes, often in
PO 00000
Frm 00024
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
35625
mathematical or statistical terms. The
basis can also be physical or conceptual.
Opportunity cost means the value of
the next best alternative to a particular
activity or resource.
Publicly available means lawfully
available to the general public from
federal, state, or local government
records; the internet; widely distributed
media; or disclosures to the general
public that are required to be made by
federal, state, or local law.
Regulatory options means, at a
minimum:
(1) The proposed or finalized option;
(2) A more stringent option which
accomplishes the stated objectives of the
Clean Air Act and that achieves
additional benefits (and presumably
costs more) beyond those realized by the
proposed or finalized option; and
(3) A less stringent option which
accomplishes the stated objectives of the
Clean Air Act and that costs less (and
presumably generates fewer benefits)
than the proposed or finalized option.
Sensitivity Analysis means an analysis
that is used to assess how the final
results or other aspects of an analysis
change as input parameters change,
particularly when only point estimates
of parameters are available. Typically, a
sensitivity analysis measures how a
model’s output changes as one of the
input parameters change. Joint
sensitivity analysis (varying more than
one parameter at a time) is sometimes
useful as well.
Significant regulation means a
proposed or final regulation that is
determined to be a ‘‘significant
regulatory action’’ pursuant to Section
3(f) E.O. 12866 or is otherwise
designated as significant by the
Administrator.
Social benefits, or benefits, means the
positive changes in societal well-being
incurred as a result of the regulation or
policy action.
Social costs, or costs, means the sum
of all opportunity costs, or reductions in
societal well-being, incurred as a result
of the regulation or policy action.
§ 83.2 How do the provisions of this
subpart apply?
(a) The provisions of this subpart
apply to benefit-cost analyses (BCA)
prepared for all future significant
regulations under the Clean Air Act
(CAA). Except where explicitly stated
otherwise, the provisions of this subpart
do not apply to any other type of agency
action, including individual party
adjudications, enforcement activities, or
permit proceedings.
(b) [Reserved]
E:\FR\FM\11JNP1.SGM
11JNP1
35626
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 113 / Thursday, June 11, 2020 / Proposed Rules
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with PROPOSALS
§ 83.3 What requirements apply to EPA’s
preparations of Benefit-Cost Analyses
(BCAs) under the Clean Air Act?
(a) Except as otherwise provided in
paragraph (b) of this section, the Agency
must develop BCAs of significant CAA
regulations in accordance with best
available scientific information and best
practices from the economic,
engineering, physical, and biological
sciences, including the following
practices.
(1) In preparing the BCA, the Agency
must include:
(i) A statement of need;
(ii) An examination of regulatory
options; and
(iii) To the extent feasible, an
assessment of all benefits and costs of
these regulatory options relative to the
baseline scenario.
(2) In preparing the BCA, the Agency
must include a statement of need that
provides: A clear description of the
problem being addressed, the reasons
for and significance of any failure of by
private markets or public institutions
causing this problem, and the
compelling need for federal government
intervention in the market to correct the
problem.
(3) In preparing the BCA the Agency
must analyze the benefits and costs of
regulatory options, as well as the
benefits and costs of other notable
deviations from the proposed for which
the Agency is soliciting comment or the
finalized option. Where there is a
continuum of options (such as options
that vary in stringency), the Agency
must analyze at least three regulatory
options (as provided in section
XX(a)(3)(i)) and explain why these were
selected.
If fewer than three options are
analyzed, or if there is a continuum of
options and the options analyzed do not
include at least one more stringent and
one less stringent option than the
proposed or finalized option, then the
Agency must explain why it is not
appropriate to analyze more options.
(4) In preparing the BCA, the Agency
must use a baseline that appropriately
considers relevant factors and relies on
transparent and reasonable
assumptions. The factors for which the
Agency must account in the baseline
include, but are not limited to, the
following:
(i) Exogenous changes in the economy
that may affect benefits and costs (e.g.,
changes in demographics, economic
activity, consumer preferences, or
technology);
(ii) Regulations promulgated by the
Agency or other government entities;
and
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:51 Jun 10, 2020
Jkt 250001
(iii) The degree of compliance by
regulated entities with other regulations.
In rulemaking actions where the
Agency determines it is appropriate to
consider more than one baseline (e.g.,
one that accounts for another EPA
regulation being developed at the same
time that affects the same environmental
condition), the Agency must provide a
reasoned explanation for the baselines
used and must identify the key
uncertainties in the forecast(s).
(5) In preparing the BCA, the Agency
must rely on the use of a framework that
is appropriate for the characteristics of
the regulation being evaluated and must
provide an explanation for the approach
adopted.
(6) The Agency must consider how
costs and benefits may be affected by
consumer and producer behavior in the
baseline and potential behavioral
changes from the policy scenarios.
(7) During the estimation of benefits,
the Agency must link regulatory
requirements to the value that
individuals place on the change in
benefit endpoints that can be
meaningfully attributed to those
requirements. The Agency must select
benefit endpoints that the scientific
evidence indicates there is:
(i) A clear causal or likely causal
relationship between pollutant exposure
and effect, and subsequently; and
(ii) An anticipated change in that
effect in response to changes in
environmental quality or exposures
expected as a result of the regulation
under analysis. The Agency must
quantify effects for endpoints which
scientific evidence is robust enough to
support such quantification.
(8) The Agency must, to the extent
supported by scientific literature as well
as practicable in a given rulemaking:
(i) Quantify all benefits;
(ii) Monetize all the benefits by
following well-defined economic
principles using well-established
economic methods; and
(iii) Qualitatively characterize benefits
that cannot be quantified or monetized.
(9) When selecting and quantifying
health endpoints in a BCA, the Agency
must:
(i) Explain the basis for significant
judgments, assumptions, data, models,
and inferences used or relied upon in
the assessment or decision;
(ii) Describe the sources, extent and
magnitude of significant uncertainties
associated with the assessment;
(iii) When selecting concentrationresponse relationships from the
scientific literature, the Agency must
select from studies where each selected
study meets the criteria in paragraphs
(b)(8)(iii)(A) through (C) of this section.
PO 00000
Frm 00025
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
(A) The study was externally and
independently peer-reviewed consistent
with Federal guidance;
(B) The pollutant analyzed in the
study matches the pollutant of interest
in the regulation;
(C) Concentration-response functions
must be parameterized from
scientifically robust studies;
(D) When an epidemiological study is
used further criteria include that the
study must assess the influence of
confounders, that the study location
must be appropriately matched to the
analysis, and that the study population
characteristics must be sufficiently
similar to those of the analysis.
(iv) When multiple studies satisfy
these criteria the Agency must
characterize multiple concentrationresponse functions, and, if appropriate,
combine them as a means of providing
a broader representation of the effect
estimate. The Agency would also
include studies that meet the criteria
above and that do not find a significant
concentration-response relationship.
(v) The Agency must base decisions
about the choice of the number of
alternative concentration-response
functions quantified for each endpoint
on the extent to which it is technically
feasible to quantify alternative
concentration-response relationships
given the available data and resources.
(vi) The Agency must select and
clearly identify concentration-response
functions with the strongest scientific
evidence, as well as evidence necessary
to demonstrate the sensitivity of the
choice of the concentration-response
function on the magnitude and the
uncertainty associated with air
pollution-attributable effects.
(vii) Once the Agency has identified
the concentration-response functions to
be used for quantifying the selected
health endpoints, the Agency must
characterize, in a BCA or related
technical support document:
(A) The variability in the
concentration-response functions across
studies and models, including plausible
alternatives;
(B) The assumptions, defaults, and
uncertainties, their rationale, and their
influence on the resulting estimates;
(C) The extent to which scientific
literature suggests that the nature of the
effect may vary across demographic or
health characteristics;
(D) The potential variability of the
concentration-response function over
the range in concentrations of interest
for the given policy;
(E) The influence of potential
confounders on the reported risk
coefficient;
E:\FR\FM\11JNP1.SGM
11JNP1
jbell on DSKJLSW7X2PROD with PROPOSALS
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 113 / Thursday, June 11, 2020 / Proposed Rules
(F) The likelihood that the parameters
of the concentration-response differ
based on geographic location; and
(G) Attributes that affect the
suitability of the study or model for
informing a risk assessment, including
the age of the air quality data, and the
generalizability of the study population.
(viii) When feasible, the Agency must
use a probability distribution of risk
when determining expected benefits.
When it is infeasible to estimate a
distribution, the Agency must use
measures of the central tendency of risk.
Upper-bound risk estimates must not be
used unless they are presented in
conjunction with lower bound and
central tendency estimates.
(10) The Agency must identify
uncertainties underlying the estimation
of both benefits and costs and, to the
extent feasible, quantitatively analyze
those that are most influential; and must
present benefits and cost estimates in
ways that convey their uncertainty. The
Agency must provide a reasoned
explanation for the scope and specific
quantitative or qualitative methods
chosen to analyze uncertainties.
(i) To the extent feasible, the Agency
must use quantitative methods to
analyze uncertainties that have the
largest potential effect on benefits or
cost estimates.
(ii) The Agency must characterize,
preferably quantitatively, sources of
uncertainty in the assessment of costs,
changes in air quality, assessment of
likely changes in health and welfare
endpoints, and the valuation of those
changes.
(iii) Where data are sufficient to do so,
the Agency must consider sources of
uncertainty both independently and
jointly.
(iv) To the extent feasible, the Agency
must also consider, and transparently
acknowledge, the extent to which
qualitatively-assessed costs or benefits
are characterized by uncertainty.
(v) Where probability distributions for
relevant input assumptions are
available, characterize significant
sources of uncertainty in the
assessment, and can be feasibly and
credibly combined, the Agency must
characterize how the probability
distributions of the relevant input
assumption uncertainty would impact
the resulting distribution of benefit and
cost estimates.
(vi) Except as provided in this
paragraph, the Agency must provide
expected-value estimates of benefits and
costs as well as distributions about each
of the estimates. In cases where
estimates based on expected values are
not feasible, the Agency must present a
plausible range of benefits and costs.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:51 Jun 10, 2020
Jkt 250001
(11) In presenting the results of the
BCA the Agency must include the
following elements:
(i) The Agency must present the
overall results of the BCA (benefits,
costs, and net benefits of each regulatory
option evaluated in the BCA) in a
manner designed to be objective,
comprehensive, reproducible to the
extent reasonably possible, and easily
understood by the public.
(ii) The Agency must describe how
the benefits and costs were estimated in
the BCA, including the assumptions
made for the analysis. The Agency must
describe the models, data, and
assumptions used to estimate benefits
and costs, and the evaluation and
selection process for these analytical
decisions. The Agency must provide an
explanation of procedures used to select
among input parameters to the benefit
and cost models, and any methods used
to quantify risk and to model fate and
transport of pollutants.
(iii) Consistent with the best available
scientific information, the Agency must
discuss non-monetized and nonquantified benefits and costs of the
action. The Agency must present
available evidence on non-monetized
and non-quantified benefits and costs,
including explanations as to why they
are not being monetized or quantified
and discussions of what the potential
impact of those benefits and costs might
be on the overall results of the BCA.
(iv) The Agency must assess the
sources of uncertainty that are likely to
have a substantial effect on the results
of the BCA and present the results of
this assessment. The Agency must
identify any data and models used to
analyze uncertainty in the BCA, and the
quality of the available data shall be
discussed.
(12) To the extent permitted by law,
the Agency must ensure that all
information (including data and models)
used in the development of the BCA is
publicly available. If the data and
models are proprietary, the Agency
must make available, to the extent
permitted by law, the underlying inputs
and assumptions used, equations, and
methodologies used by EPA, while
continuing to provide appropriate
protection for information claimed as
confidential business information (CBI),
personally identifiable information (PII),
and other privileged, non-exempt
information.
(b) The Agency must provide a
reasoned explanation for any departures
from best practices in the BCA,
including a discussion of the likely
effect of the departures on the results of
the BCA.
PO 00000
Frm 00026
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
35627
§ 83.4 What additional requirements apply
to EPA’s presentation of BCA results for all
significant rules promulgated under the
Clean Air Act?
(a) The Agency must provide, in
addition to the reporting of the overall
results of the BCA as specified in § l._
(a)(11)(i), a summary in the preamble of
the overall BCA results, including total
costs, benefits, and net benefits.
(b) The Agency must provide an
additional presentation in the preamble
of the public health and welfare benefits
that pertain to the specific objective (or
objectives, as the case may be) of the
CAA provision or provisions under
which the rule is promulgated.
(1)This presentation must list the
benefit categories arising from the
environmental improvement that is
targeted by the relevant statutory
provision and report the monetized
value to society of these benefits.
(2) If these benefit categories cannot
be monetized, the Agency must report
the quantified estimates of these
benefits to the extent possible and
provide a qualitative characterization if
they cannot be quantified.
(c) When the CAA provision or
provisions under which the rule is
promulgated contemplate the
consideration of specific costs, the
Agency must provide a transparent
presentation of how those specific costs
relate to total costs, to the extent
possible.
(d) The presentations specified in
paragraphs (a), (b), and (c) of this
section must be placed in the same
section in the preamble of the
regulation.
[FR Doc. 2020–12535 Filed 6–10–20; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6560–50–P
FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS
COMMISSION
47 CFR Part 54
[WT Docket Nos. 18–122; Report No. 3149;
FRS 16834 ]
Petitions for Reconsideration of Action
in Proceedings
Federal Communications
Commission.
ACTION: Petitions for Reconsideration.
AGENCY:
Petitions for Reconsideration
(Petitions) have been filed in the
Commission’s proceeding by David
Silver, on behalf of Aerospace Industries
Association et al., Howard J. Symons, on
behalf of Charter Communications Inc.,
Laura H. Phillips, on behalf of Intelsat
License LLC, Patrick Masambu, on
behalf of International
SUMMARY:
E:\FR\FM\11JNP1.SGM
11JNP1
Agencies
[Federal Register Volume 85, Number 113 (Thursday, June 11, 2020)]
[Proposed Rules]
[Pages 35612-35627]
From the Federal Register Online via the Government Publishing Office [www.gpo.gov]
[FR Doc No: 2020-12535]
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION AGENCY
40 CFR Part 83
[EPA-HQ-OAR-2020-00044; FRL 10010-62-OAR]
RIN 2060-AU51
Increasing Consistency and Transparency in Considering Benefits
and Costs in the Clean Air Act Rulemaking Process
AGENCY: Environmental Protection Agency (EPA).
ACTION: Notice of proposed rulemaking.
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
SUMMARY: The Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) is proposing
processes that it would be required to undertake in promulgating
regulations under the Clean Air Act (CAA) to ensure that information
regarding the benefits and costs of regulatory decisions is provided
and considered in a consistent and transparent manner. This proposed
rulemaking addresses, among other things, issues raised in the June 13,
2018 advance notice of proposed rulemaking, ``Increasing Consistency
and Transparency in Considering Costs and Benefits in the Rulemaking
Process,'' and proposes how the concepts described in that advance
document would be implemented in rulemakings conducted by the EPA using
its authorities under the CAA. The EPA is proposing to establish
procedural requirements governing the development and presentation of
benefit-cost analyses (BCA), including risk assessments used in the
BCA, for significant rulemakings conducted under the CAA. Together,
these requirements would help ensure that the EPA implements its
statutory obligations under the CAA, and describes its work in
implementing those obligations, in a way that is consistent and
transparent.
DATES: Comments must be received on or before July 27, 2020.
Public Hearing: The EPA will hold one or more virtual public
hearings on this proposed rulemaking. These will be announced in a
separate Federal Register publication that provides details, including
specific dates, times, and contact information for these hearings.
ADDRESSES: You may send comments, identified by Docket ID No. EPA-HQ-
OAR-2020-00044, by any of the following methods:
Federal eRulemaking Portal: https://www.regulations.gov/
(our preferred method). Follow the online instructions for submitting
comments.
Instructions: All submissions received must include the Docket ID
No. EPA-HQ-OAR-2020-00044 for this rulemaking. Comments received may be
posted without change to https://www.regulations.gov/, including any
personal information provided. For detailed instructions on sending
comments and additional information on the rulemaking process, see the
``Public Participation'' heading of the SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION
section of this document. Out of an abundance of caution for members of
the public and our staff, the EPA Docket Center and Reading Room was
closed to public visitors on March 31, 2020, to reduce the risk of
transmitting COVID-19. Our Docket Center staff will continue to provide
remote customer service via email, phone, and webform. We encourage the
public to submit comments via https://www.regulations.gov or email, as
there is a temporary suspension of mail delivery to EPA, and no hand
deliveries are currently accepted. For further information on EPA
Docket Center services and the current status, please visit us online
at https://www.epa.gov/dockets.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: Leif Hockstad, Office of Air Policy
and Program Support, Office of Air and Radiation, Environmental
Protection Agency, Mail Code 6103A,1200 Pennsylvania Avenue NW,
Washington, DC 20460; (202) 343-9432; email address:
[email protected].
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: Organization of this document. The following
outline is provided to aid in locating information in this preamble.
I. Public Participation
II. General Information
A. Does this action apply to me?
B. What is the Agency's authority for taking this action?
C. What action is the Agency taking?
III. Background
IV. Rationale and Summary of the Proposed Requirements
A. Preparation of Benefit-Cost Analyses for Significant
Regulations
B. Best Practices for the Development of Benefit-Cost Analysis
C. Requirement for Additional Presentations of BCA Results in
Rulemakings
V. Additional Considerations and Requests for Comment
A. Specifying How BCA Results Should Inform Regulatory Decisions
B. Other Areas of Solicitation for Public Comment
VI. References
VII. Statutory and Executive Order Reviews
I. Public Participation
A. Written Comments
Submit your comments, identified by Docket ID No. EPA-HQ-OAR-2020-
00044, at https://www.regulations.gov (our preferred method), or the
other methods identified in the ADDRESSES section. Once submitted,
comments cannot be edited or removed from the docket. The EPA may
publish any comment received to its public docket. Do not submit
electronically any information you consider to be Confidential Business
Information (CBI) or other information whose disclosure is restricted
by statute. Multimedia submissions (audio, video, etc.) must be
accompanied by a written comment. The written comment is considered the
official comment and should include discussion of all points you wish
to make. The EPA will generally not consider comments or comment
contents located outside of the primary submission (i.e. on the web,
cloud, or other file sharing system). For additional submission
methods, the full EPA public comment policy, information about CBI or
multimedia submissions, and general guidance on making effective
comments, please visit https://www.epa.gov/dockets/commenting-epa-dockets.
The EPA is temporarily suspending its Docket Center and Reading
Room for public visitors to reduce the risk of transmitting COVID-19.
Written comments submitted by mail are temporarily suspended and no
hand
[[Page 35613]]
deliveries will be accepted. Our Docket Center staff will continue to
provide remote customer service via email, phone, and webform. We
encourage the public to submit comments via https://www.regulations.gov. For further information and updates on EPA Docket
Center services, please visit us online at https://www.epa.gov/dockets.
The EPA continues to carefully and continuously monitor information
from the Centers for Disease Control and Prevention (CDC), local area
health departments, and our Federal partners so that we can respond
rapidly as conditions change regarding COVID-19.
B. Public Hearing
The EPA will hold one or more virtual public hearings on this
proposed rulemaking. These will be announced in a separate Federal
Register publication that provides details, including specific dates,
times, and contact information for these hearings. Please note that EPA
is deviating from its typical approach because the President has
declared a national emergency. Because of current CDC recommendations,
as well as state and local orders for social distancing to limit the
spread of COVID-19, EPA cannot hold in-person public meetings at this
time.
II. General Information
A. Does this action apply to me?
This proposed regulation does not regulate the conduct or determine
the rights of any entity or individual outside the Agency, as this
action pertains only to internal EPA practices. However, the Agency
recognizes that any entity or individual interested in EPA's
regulations may be interested in this proposal. For example, this
proposal may be of particular interest to entities and individuals
concerned with how EPA conducts benefit and cost analyses.
B. What is the Agency's authority for taking this action?
The Agency proposes to take this action under the CAA using 42
U.S.C. 7601(a)(1). Section 301(a)(1) of the CAA provides authority to
the Administrator ``to prescribe such regulations as are necessary to
carry out his functions'' under the CAA. Such authority extends to
internal agency procedures that increase the Agency's ability to
provide consistency and transparency to the public in regard to the
rulemaking process under the CAA. The EPA solicits comment on whether
additional or alternative sources of authority are appropriate bases
for this proposed regulation.
This is a proposed rulemaking of agency organization, procedure or
practice. This proposed procedural rule would not regulate any person
or entity outside the EPA and would not affect the rights or
obligations of outside parties. As a rule of Agency procedure, this
rule is exempt from the notice and comment requirements set forth in
the Administrative Procedure Act. See 5 U.S.C. 553(b)(A). Nonetheless,
the Agency voluntarily seeks comment because it believes that the
information and opinions supplied by the public will inform the
Agency's views.
The D.C. Circuit has explained that ``the critical feature of a
rule that satisfies the so-called procedural exception [to the APA's
notice and comment requirements] is that it covers agency actions that
do not themselves alter the rights or interests of parties . . . .''
James A. Hurson Assocs. v. Glickman, 229 F.3d 277, 280 (D.C. Cir.
2000); National Mining Association v. McCarthy, 758 F.3d 243 (D.C. Cir.
2014) (holding that EPA's interagency plan for enhanced consultation
and coordination is a procedural rule because it does not alter the
rights or interests of parties, although it may alter the manner in
which the parties present themselves or their viewpoints to the
Agency); Batterton v. Marshall, 648 F.2d 708 (D.C. Cir. 1980) (``The
critical question is whether the agency action jeopardizes the rights
and interests of parties.''). This rule would not regulate the conduct
or determine the rights of any entity outside the federal government.
C. What action is the Agency Taking?
This proposed action consists of three elements. First, the
proposed regulation provides that the EPA will prepare a BCA for all
future significant proposed and final regulations under the CAA.
Second, the EPA proposes that the BCA be developed using the best
available scientific information and in accordance with best practices
from the economic, engineering, physical, and biological sciences.
Third, the EPA proposes additional procedural requirements to increase
transparency in the presentation of the BCA results, while maintaining
the standard practices of measuring net benefits consistent with E.O.
12866. Together, these requirements would help ensure that the EPA
implements its statutory obligations under the CAA in a way that is
consistent and transparent. In this document, the EPA solicits comment
on all aspects of this proposal and how it can best be implemented in
accordance with existing law and prior statements of policy that have
called for increasing consistency and transparency. Each of the key
elements of the action is discussed in more detail below, followed by a
summary of specific solicitations for comment.
III. Background
As the EPA works to advance its mission of protecting public health
and the environment, it seeks to ensure that its analyses of regulatory
decisions provided to the public continue to be rooted in sound,
transparent and consistent approaches to evaluating benefits and costs.
The Supreme Court noted in Michigan v. EPA that ``[c]onsideration
of cost reflects the understanding that reasonable regulation
ordinarily requires paying attention to the advantages and the
disadvantages of agency decisions.'' Michigan v. EPA, 135 U.S. 2699,
2707 (2015). Many environmental statutes, including the CAA,
contemplate the consideration of costs as part of regulatory decision-
making in many instances. Several of these statutes, including the CAA,
contain provisions that explicitly require some form of cost
consideration when establishing a standard. Additionally, several other
provisions use terminology that in context implicitly direct the EPA to
consider costs, alone or in conjunction with benefits and other
factors. For example, section 112(n)(1)(A) of the CAA directs the
Administrator to ``regulate electric utility steam generating units
under [section 112], if the Administrator finds such regulation is
appropriate and necessary.'' ``Read naturally in the present context,
the phrase `appropriate and necessary' requires at least some attention
to cost.'' Michigan, 135 S. Ct. at 2707 (2015). Therefore, in light of
the varying statutory provisions in the CAA that apply to or otherwise
address cost consideration, the Agency proposes to provide analysis to
the public that will present all of the benefits and costs in a
consistent manner for all significant CAA rulemakings.
Thorough and careful economic analysis is informative for
developing sound environmental policies. High quality economic analyses
enhance the effectiveness of environmental policy decisions by
providing policy makers and the public with information needed to
systematically assess the likely consequences of various actions or
options. BCA, a type of economic analysis, can serve an integral
informative role in the regulatory development process. In general
terms, a BCA is an evaluation of both the benefits and costs to society
as a result of a policy and the difference between the two (i.e., the
calculation of net benefits (benefits minus costs)). It provides
information about whether a
[[Page 35614]]
policy change has the potential to improve the aggregate well-being of
society.
The usefulness of BCA in informing the development of environmental
regulations has been recognized both within and outside government for
decades. As discussed below, Presidential Executive Orders and statutes
have been in place for decades formally requiring the preparation of
BCA in the development of major Federal regulations, and the courts
have examined the use of BCA in several regulatory contexts. In
addition, the usefulness of formal BCA in informing regulatory policy
debates on protecting and improving public health, safety, and the
natural environment has been emphasized in the academic literature. For
example, as explained in seminal work by prominent economists Arrow et
al. (1996a, 1996b), BCA ``can provide an exceptionally useful framework
for consistently organizing disparate information, and in this way, it
can greatly improve the process and, hence, the outcome of policy
analysis. If properly done, BCA can be of great help to agencies
participating in the development of environmental regulations . . .''
(1996b). Arrow et al. recommend that ``Benefit-cost analysis should be
required for all major regulatory decisions,'' and that ``the precise
definition of `major' requires judgment.''
Benefit-cost analyses have been an integral part of executive
branch rulemaking for decades. Presidents since the 1970s have issued
executive orders requiring agencies to conduct analysis of the economic
consequences of regulations as part of the rulemaking development
process. President Ford's 1974 Executive Order (E.O.) 11821 required
government agencies to prepare inflation impact statements before
issuing major regulations.\1\ These inflation impact statements
essentially turned into benefit-cost analyses based on the
understanding that a regulation would not be truly inflationary unless
its costs to society exceeded the benefits it produced,\2\ and the E.O.
was renamed as Economic Impact Statements with E.O. 11949 in 1976.\3\
President Carter's 1978 E.O. 12044, Improving Government Regulations,
included formal requirements for conducting regulatory analysis at a
minimum ``for all regulations which will result in (a) an annual effect
on the economy of $100 million or more; or (b) a major increase in
costs or prices for individual industries, levels of government or
geographic regions.'' \4\ Regulatory analyses under E.O. 12044 were
required to contain ``a succinct statement of the problem; a
description of the major alternative ways of dealing with the problem
that were considered by the agency; an analysis of the economic
consequences of each of these alternatives and a detailed explanation
of the reasons for choosing one alternative over the others.''
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1\ Executive Order 11821 -- Inflation Impact Statements,
Federal Register, Vol. 39, No. 231--Friday, November 29, 1974 (pages
41501-41502).
\2\ https://obamawhitehouse.archives.gov/omb/inforeg_chap1#tnfrp.
\3\ Executive Order 11949--Economic Impact Statements, Federal
Register, Vol. 42, No. 3-- Wednesday, January 5, 1977 (page 1017).
https://www.govinfo.gov/content/pkg/FR-1977-01-05/pdf/FR-1977-01-05.pdf.
\4\ Executive Order 12044--Improving Government Regulations,
Federal Register, Vol. 43, No. 58--Friday, March 24, 1978 (pages
12659-12670).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
In 1981, President Reagan issued E.O. 12291, Federal Regulation,
which imposed the first requirements for conducting formal benefit-cost
analysis in the development of new major Federal regulations. Among its
provisions, it explicitly required that: ``(a) Administrative decisions
shall be based on adequate information concerning the need for and
consequences of proposed government action; (b) Regulatory action shall
not be undertaken unless the potential benefits to society for the
regulation outweigh the potential costs to society; (c) Regulatory
objectives shall be chosen to maximize the net benefits to society; (d)
Among alternative approaches to any given regulatory objective, the
alternative involving the least net cost to society shall be chosen;
and (e) Agencies shall set regulatory priorities with the aim of
maximizing the aggregate net benefits to society, taking into account
the condition of the particular industries affected by regulations, the
condition of the national economy, and other regulatory actions
contemplated for the future.'' Under E.O. 12291, major regulations
included ``any regulation that is likely to result in: (1) An annual
effect on the economy of $100 million or more; (2) A major increase in
costs or prices for consumers, individual industries, Federal, State,
or local government agencies, or geographic regions; or (3) Significant
adverse effects on competition, employment, investment, productivity,
innovation, or on the ability of United States-based enterprises to
compete with foreign-based enterprises in domestic or export markets.''
\5\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\5\ https://www.archives.gov/federal-register/codification/executive-order/12291.html.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
In 1993, E.O. 12291 was revoked and replaced by President Clinton's
E.O. 12866, Regulatory Planning and Review, which is still in effect
today. E.O. 12866 requires that for all significant regulatory actions
pursuant to Section 3(f), an agency provide ``an assessment of the
potential costs and benefits of the regulatory action, including an
explanation of the manner in which the regulatory action is consistent
with a statutory mandate . . .'' For regulatory actions meeting
criteria listed under Section 3(f)(1)--that is, any regulatory action
that is ``likely to result in a rule that may . . . have an annual
effect on the economy of $100 million or more or adversely affect in a
material way the economy, a sector of the economy, productivity,
competition, jobs, the environment, public health or safety, or State,
local, or tribal governments or communities''--E.O. 12866 further
requires that this assessment include a quantification of benefits and
costs to the extent feasible. In addition, E.O. 12866 states that, to
the extent permitted by law, agencies ``should assess both the costs
and the benefits of the intended regulation and, recognizing that some
costs and benefits are difficult to quantify, propose or adopt a
regulation only upon a reasoned determination that the benefits of the
intended regulation justify its costs''; ``in choosing among
alternative regulatory approaches . . . should select those approaches
that maximize net benefits (including potential economic,
environmental, public health and safety, and other advantages;
distributive impacts; and equity), unless a statute requires another
regulatory approach''; and that ``[e]ach agency shall base its
decisions on the best reasonably obtainable scientific, technical,
economic, and other information concerning the need for, and
consequences of, the intended regulation.''
In 1995, the Unfunded Mandates Reform Act of 1995 (UMRA) included
analytical requirements for all regulatory actions that include federal
mandates ``that may result in the expenditure by State, local, and
tribal governments, in the aggregate, or by the private sector, of $100
million or more (adjusted annually for inflation) in any one year.'' An
action contains a federal mandate if it imposes an enforceable duty on
state, local or tribal governments, or the private sector. The
analytical requirements under UMRA are similar to the analytical
requirements under E.O. 12866, and thus the same analysis may permit
[[Page 35615]]
compliance with both analytical requirements.
More recent Executive Orders also reaffirm the requirements and
principles in E.O. 12866. The former Administration's E.O. 13563,
issued in 2011 and also still in effect today, reaffirms the
requirements and other principles and definitions in E.O. 12866 and
embraces benefit-cost analysis: ``In applying these principles, each
agency is directed to use the best available techniques to quantify
anticipated present and future benefits and costs as accurately as
possible.'' \6\ More recently, this Administration's E.O. 13777, issued
in 2017, directs agencies to identify regulations that ``impose costs
that exceed benefits.'' \7\ E.O. 13783, also issued in 2017, similarly
reaffirms the importance of benefit-cost analysis: ``In order to ensure
sound regulatory decision making, it is essential that agencies use
estimates of costs and benefits in their regulatory analyses that are
based on the best available science and economics.'' \8\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\6\ https://obamawhitehouse.archives.gov/the-press-office/2011/01/18/executive-order-13563-improving-regulation-and-regulatory-review.
\7\ Enforcing the Regulatory Reform Agenda (82 FR 12285, March
1, 2017).
\8\ https://www.govinfo.gov/content/pkg/FR-2017-03-31/pdf/2017-06576.pdf.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The Office of Management and Budget's (OMB's) Circular A-4 (OMB
2003), which remains in effect today, provides guidance to Federal
agencies on the development of regulatory analysis as required under
E.O. 12866 and a variety of related authorities.\9\ In developing
Circular A-4, OMB first developed a draft that was subject to public
comment, interagency review, and external peer review. As summarized in
E.O. 13783, ``. . . OMB Circular A-4 . . . was issued after peer review
and public comment and has been widely accepted for more than a decade
as embodying the best practices for conducting regulatory cost-benefit
analysis.'' \10\ The document encourages transparency in practices,
including the expression of costs and benefits in monetary units that
allow for the evaluation of ``incremental benefits and costs of
successively more stringent regulatory alternatives'' such that an
agency can ``maximize net benefits.'' \11\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\9\ https://obamawhitehouse.archives.gov/omb/circulars_a004_a-4/. Circular A-4 refines and replaces OMB's ``best practices''
document of 1996, which was issued as a guidance in 2000 and
reaffirmed in 2001. All these versions of the 1996 document were
superseded by Circular A-4.
\10\ https://www.govinfo.gov/content/pkg/FR-2017-03-31/pdf/2017-06576.pdf.
\11\ https://obamawhitehouse.archives.gov/omb/circulars_a004_a-4/.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
EPA's Guidelines for Preparing Economic Analyses (hereafter, the
Guidelines) \12\ complements Circular A-4 by providing the Agency with
more detailed peer-reviewed guidance on how to conduct BCA and other
types of economic analyses for both environmental regulatory actions
and non-regulatory management strategies, with the intent of improving
compliance with E.O. 12866 and other executive orders and statutory
requirements (e.g., Small Business Regulatory Enforcement Fairness Act
of 1996 provisions). The Guidelines are updated periodically--building
on work issued in 1983 (then titled Guidelines for Performing
Regulatory Impact Analysis), 2000, and most recently in 2010--to
account for growth and development of economic tools and practices. The
Guidelines establish a scientific framework for analyzing the benefits,
costs, and other economic impacts of regulations and policies,
including assessing the distribution of costs and benefits among
various segments of the population. In addition to presenting the well-
established scientific foundations for economic analysis, they
incorporate recent advances in theoretical and applied work in the
field of environmental economics. Updates of the Guidelines are led by
the EPA's National Center for Environmental Economics (NCEE) in
consultation with economists from across the Agency and OMB. All
chapters undergo an external peer review, either through EPA's Science
Advisory Board or through independent reviews by external experts,
prior to be being finalized.\13\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\12\ https://www.epa.gov/environmental-economics/guidelines-preparing-economic-analyses.
\13\ The EPA is in the process of a periodic update of the
Guidelines. The EPA anticipates that among the changes within this
update, the current Section 9.2.3.3, ``Impacts on employment'', will
be replaced with a discussion based on more recent literature and
feedback from the Economy Wide Modeling Science Advisory Board
Panel. For more details regarding Chapter 9, see: https://www.epa.gov/sites/production/files/2017-09/documents/ee-0568-09.pdf.
For more details regarding the update of the Guidelines in general,
see: https://yosemite.epa.gov/sab/sabproduct.nsf//LookupWebProjectsCurrentBOARD/30D5E59E8DC91C2285258403006EEE00?OpenDocument.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Given the history described above pertaining to the use of BCA by
executive agencies, and given that several statutes, including the CAA,
include provisions that require some form of cost consideration, the
federal courts have also developed significant case law regarding
regulatory cost consideration and the usefulness of BCA. This case law
addresses when, and if, such use is required or permissible and how it
may be employed in reasoned decision-making. As a general matter, while
certain statutory provisions may prohibit reliance on BCA or other
methods of cost consideration in decision making,\14\ such provisions
do not preclude the Agency from providing additional information
regarding a proposed or final rule to the public. For example, while
the CAA prohibits the EPA from considering cost when establishing
requisite National Ambient Air Quality Standards (NAAQS) for criteria
pollutants,\15\ the EPA nonetheless provides Regulatory Impact Analyses
(RIAs) \16\ to the public for these rulemakings.\17\ The agency
believes that the information provided as a result of the procedural
requirements of this proposal, if finalized, would increase
transparency and consistency across CAA rulemakings; would provide the
public with additional information in the CAA rulemaking process; and
would provide the Agency with supplemental information for potential
use by the Agency when it is appropriate to be considered. Whether the
Agency utilizes any information produced as a result of these
procedural requirements would be determined by the statutes and
regulations governing particular subsequent rulemakings. Any such
information would be in addition to the information provided by other
methodologies and analyses as directed by specific CAA statutes and
regulations.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\14\ See, e.g., Whitman v. Am. Trucking Ass'ns, 531 U.S. 457
(2001) (holding that Section 109(b) of the CAA unambiguously barred
cost considerations when setting the National Ambient Air Quality
Standards.
\15\ Id.
\16\ A regulatory impact analysis, or ``regulatory analysis''
for brevity, as prepared under E.O. 12866, consists of a benefit-
cost analysis and any related cost-effectiveness analyses and
assessments of economic and distributional impacts (OMB 2003).
\17\ See, e.g., U.S. EPA, Regulatory Impact Analysis of the
Proposed Revisions to the National Ambient Air Quality Standards for
Ground-Level Ozone (2014), https://www3.epa.gov/ttn/ecas/regdata/RIAs/20141125ria.pdf.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The Supreme Court has held that agencies may conduct and consider a
BCA even when a statute does not explicitly require one. In Entergy
Corp. v. Riverkeeper, Inc., 556 U.S. 208, 222-224 (2009), the Supreme
Court clarified that neither American Textile Mfrs. Inst. v. Donovan,
452 U.S. 490 (1981) (American Textile Mfrs.) nor Whitman v. Am.
Trucking Ass'ns, 531 U.S. 457 (2001) (American Trucking), stands for
the broad proposition that statutory silence in regard to BCA always
implies prohibition of BCA. Concluding that the EPA is permitted to use
BCA in determining the content of regulations promulgated under Clean
Water Act section 1326(b). The Court reasoned
[[Page 35616]]
``that [CWA] Sec. 1326(b)'s silence is meant to convey nothing more
than a refusal to tie the agency's hands as to whether cost-benefit
analysis should be used, and if so to what degree.'' Id. at 222; see
also id. at 212, 219-20, 226.
The Supreme Court noted that its decisions in American Trucking and
American Textile Mfrs. ``do not undermine this conclusion.'' 556 U.S.
at 223. The Court highlighted that in American Trucking, it had held
that the text of section 109 of the Clean Air Act, ``interpreted in its
statutory and historical context . . . unambiguously bars cost
considerations'' when air quality standards are set pursuant to that
provision. American Trucking, 531 U.S. at 471, quoted in Entergy Corp.,
556 U.S. at 223. The Entergy Corp. Court further elaborated that
``[t]he relevant 'statutory context' [in American Trucking] included
other provisions in the [CAA] that expressly authorized consideration
of costs, whereas Sec. 109 did not.'' 556 U.S. at 233. The Court
concluded that American Trucking ``stands for the rather unremarkable
proposition that sometimes statutory silence, when viewed in context,
is best interpreted as limiting agency discretion.'' 556 U.S. at 223.
The Court further noted that in American Textile, the Court had relied,
in part, on the absence of mention of BCA in the statute to hold that
the agency was not required to conduct a BCA when setting certain
health and safety standards. 556 U.S. at 223. ``[U]nder Chevron, that
an agency is not required to [engage in cost-benefit analysis] does not
mean that an agency is not permitted to do so.'' Id. Thus, the Supreme
Court has confirmed that a statute need not have explicitly required
that the agency conduct a BCA in its decision-making process for the
agency to do so.
The Supreme Court additionally acknowledged in Entergy Corp. that
``whether it is `reasonable' to bear a particular cost may well depend
on the resulting benefits.'' 556 U.S. at 225-226. This concept was
further elaborated upon by the Court in Michigan v. EPA, which held, in
the context of the term ``appropriate and necessary'' contained in
Section 112(n)(1)(A) of the CAA, that the term required consideration
of cost. 135 S. Ct. 2699, 2706 (2015). In doing so, the Supreme Court
stated that ``[o]ne would not say that it is even rational, never mind
`appropriate,' to impose billions of dollars in economic costs in
return for a few dollars in health or environmental benefits'',
concluding that ``[n]o regulation is `appropriate' if it does
significantly more harm than good.'' Id. at 2707. The D.C. Circuit
recently echoed this concept in Mingo Logan Coal Co. v. EPA. While the
D.C. Circuit panel ultimately concluded that the cost issue had been
forfeited by petitioners, in response to then Judge Kavanaugh's dissent
which argued that cost consideration should be required, the panel
stated, ``[i]ndeed, we do not quibble with his general premise--and
that of the many legal luminaries he cites--that an agency should
generally weigh the costs of its action against its benefits.'' 829
F.3d 710, 723 (D.C. Cir. 2016). In general, when cost consideration is
either required or permitted by the CAA, the courts have not mandated a
specific type of cost consideration but have granted the Agency broad
discretion in determining its methodology. Michigan, 135 S. Ct. at 2711
(``We need not and do not hold that the law unambiguously required the
Agency, when making this preliminary estimate, to conduct a formal
cost-benefit analysis in which each advantage and disadvantage is
assigned a monetary value. It will be up to the Agency to decide (as
always, within the limits of reasonable interpretation) how to account
for cost.''); see also Sierra Club v. Costle, 657 F.2d 298, 345 (D.C.
Cir. 1981) (``[S]ection 111(a) explicitly instructs the EPA to balance
multiple concerns when promulgating a NSPS.''); id. at 321 (``The text
gives the EPA broad discretion to weigh different factors in setting
the standard.''); Lignite Energy Council v. EPA, 198 F.3d 930, 933
(D.C. Cir. 1999) (``Because section 111 [of the CAA] does not set forth
the weight that [should be] assigned to each of these factors, we have
granted the agency a great degree of discretion in balancing them'');
Husqvarna AB v. EPA, 254 F.3d 195, 200 (D.C. Cir. 2001) (``Section 213
[of the CAA] . . . simply directs the EPA to consider cost. . . .
Because section 213 does not mandate a specific method of cost
analysis, we find reasonable the EPA's choice to consider costs on the
per ton of emissions removed basis.'').
Additionally, lower courts have noted the usefulness of BCA and
have utilized the information provided therein to inform their analysis
when reviewing agency regulations. Several of these cases utilize
information from agency-created BCAs and/or RIAs as evidence that an
agency ignored alternatives or acted in an arbitrary and capricious
manner when taking action.
For example, in Advocates for Highway and Auto Safety v. FMCSA, 429
F.3d. 1136 (D.C. Cir. 2005), the D.C. Circuit relied in part on a BCA
in invalidating, as arbitrary and capricious, a final rule promulgated
by Federal Motor Carrier Safety Administration (FMCSA) intended to
ensure that drivers of commercial motor vehicles received adequate
training. In its analysis, the D.C. Circuit highlighted an incongruity
between methods of training shown to be effective and the final rule,
noting that ``[f]rom a purely economic perspective, the agency's
disregard of the Adequacy Report [containing a BCA] is baffling in
light of the evidence in the record.'' Id. at 1146. The D.C. Circuit
pointed to a training regimen that ``according to the agency's own
calculations, [would] produce benefits far in excess of costs.'' Id.
Noting the agency's findings that ``the program's estimated 10-year
cost of between $4.19 billion to $4.51 billion would yield a benefit
ranging from $5.4 billion to $15.27 billion, depending on analytic
assumptions,'' the court concluded that the BCA for the rule ``lends no
support to FMCSA's position. In the final rule, FMCSA says practically
nothing about the projected benefits.'' Id.;
In Public Citizen, Inc. v. Mineta, 340 F.3d 39 (2nd Cir. 2003), the
Second Circuit determined that a National Highway Traffic Safety
Administration (NHTSA) rule regarding tire pressure monitoring system
(TPMS) requirements was arbitrary and capricious, as the NHTSA BCA
showed that alternatives would be safer and more cost-effective. The
court stated that it may ``be difficult to weigh economic costs against
safety benefits. But the difficulty of the task does not relieve the
agency of its obligation to perform it under [certain vehicle safety
laws] and State Farm.'' Id. at 58 (citing Motor Vehicles Mfrs. Ass'n v.
State Farm Mut. Auto. Ins. Co., 463 U.S. 29 (1983)). The Second Circuit
observed that NHTSA ``instead, presents us with a rulemaking record
that does not explain why the costs saved were worth the benefits
sacrificed.'' Id. The court noted that the BCA ``discloses that the
added cost for a system that worked all of the time, rather than half
of the time, was less than $10 per car, and that the adoption of the
four-tire, 25 percent standard alone was the most cost effective means
of preventing crashes caused by significantly under-inflated tires.''
Id.
Finally, in NRDC v. EPA, 824 F.2d 1258 (1st Cir. 1987), the First
Circuit vacated, in part, and remanded rules for long-term disposal of
high-level radioactive waste under Nuclear Waste Policy Act of 1982
based in part on the Agency's selection of a 1,000-year design
criterion rather than a longer-term one. The court determined that it
was unreasonable agency action to not adopt cheap methods of increasing
protections. In doing so, the court
[[Page 35617]]
observed that ``[l]ikewise, EPA's Final [RIA] of 40 CFR part 191
demonstrates that more rigorous site selection could produce sites with
such impermeable geologic media that compliance with the individual
protections for a much longer duration would not even require the extra
cost of `very good' engineered canisters.'' Id. at 1289.
With this history in mind as a backdrop and following E.O. 13777
noted above, the EPA is proposing to establish requirements to ensure
that the EPA consistently assesses the costs and benefits of
significant CAA rules. The EPA opened a public docket \18\ in April
2017 to solicit feedback and identify regulations that ``impose costs
that exceed benefits.'' Among the public comments received, a large
cross-section of stakeholders stated that the agency either
underestimated costs, overestimated benefits, or evaluated benefits and
costs inconsistently in its rulemakings. Per E.O. 13777 and based on
these public comments, the EPA decided to take further action to
evaluate opportunities for reform.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\18\ See EPA, Evaluation of Existing Regulations (82 FR 17793).
All public comments are accessible online in our docket on the
Regulations.gov website identified by Docket ID No. EPA-HQ-OA-2017-
0190.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
In June 2018, the EPA issued an Advance Notice of Proposed
Rulemaking (ANPRM), ``Increasing Consistency and Transparency in
Considering Costs and Benefits in the Rulemaking Process'' (83 FR
27524, June 13, 2018), to solicit public input on potential approaches
for increasing consistency and transparency in how the EPA considers
benefits and costs in the rulemaking process. Informed by the public
comments received on that ANPRM, on May 13, 2019, the Administrator
issued a memorandum \19\ to EPA's Assistant Administrators announcing
the intention to propose statute-specific rules that outline how
consistency and transparency concepts will be implemented in future
rulemakings. The memorandum outlined the following principles for
developing these regulatory proposals, consistent with applicable laws
and regulations: Ensuring that the Agency balances benefits and costs
in regulatory decision-making; increasing consistency in the
interpretation of statutory terminology; providing transparency in the
weight assigned to various factors in regulatory decisions; and
promoting adherence to best practices in conducting the technical
analysis used to inform decisions.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\19\ Available at: https://www.epa.gov/environmental-economics/administrator-wheeler-memorandum-increasing-consistency-and-transparency.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
This proposed rulemaking is the first statute-specific rulemaking
in this effort. The EPA is proposing to codify the procedural
requirements governing the development of BCA, including risk
assessments used as inputs to the BCA, for significant rulemakings
conducted under the CAA, and proposes additional procedural
requirements to increase transparency in the presentation of the
benefits resulting from significant CAA regulations. Together, these
requirements would ensure a consistent approach to the EPA's CAA
benefit-cost analyses under the CAA and would provide transparency by
requiring the generation of relevant information in all significant
rulemakings.
IV. Rationale and Summary of the Proposed Requirements
A. Preparation of Benefit-Cost Analyses for Significant Regulations
The EPA seeks to codify the practice of preparing BCAs in the
development of future significant CAA regulations. Specifically, EPA
proposes that all future significant proposed and final regulations
promulgated under the Clean Air Act be accompanied by a BCA. The EPA
proposes to define a significant regulation as a proposed or final
regulation that is determined to be a ``significant regulatory action''
pursuant to E.O. 12866 Section 3(f) or is otherwise designated as
significant by the Administrator. Regulations meeting either of these
factors are generally those that the EPA anticipates would have the
largest annual impact on the economy (i.e., greater than $100 million)
as well as those that are important to analyze for other policy
reasons. For example, a rule projected to have less than a $100 million
annual effect on the economy could disproportionately affect a single
industry, population subgroup, or geographic area. Such rules, or ones
that are notably novel or significant for other policy reasons, would
benefit from rigorous analysis to inform the public and decision makers
about the magnitude and disposition of both their benefits and costs on
affected entities.
B. Best Practices for the Development of Benefit-Cost Analysis
In response to the ANPRM, the EPA received comments from a wide
range of stakeholders emphasizing the importance of conducting BCA in
accordance with best practices from the economic, engineering,
physical, and biological sciences. One theme raised by some commenters
was that there is inadequate adherence to existing EPA and OMB guidance
for how to conduct BCA. Some commenters pointed to recent CAA
regulatory BCAs conducted pursuant to E.O. 12866 as examples of a lack
of transparency or improper analytic assumptions. As one example, some
commenters contend that some BCAs have double-counted benefits that
arise from another regulation. The EPA agrees that there is a risk of
such a misestimation if the pollution concentration levels resulting
from existing regulations are not carefully accounted for in the
baseline of the analysis. In other words, this type of double-counting
can be avoided if the Agency follows the best practices for BCA of
correctly specifying the baseline. Several commenters recommended that
the EPA issue binding procedural requirements to ensure transparency
and consistent adherence to best practices for BCA. This proposed
rulemaking seeks to ensure consistent adherence to best practices for
BCA of future CAA regulations by codifying these requirements into
regulation. The EPA proposes that BCAs for significant proposed and
final CAA regulations be developed in accordance with the best
available scientific information and best practices from the economic,
engineering, physical, and biological sciences. Specifically, the EPA
proposes to codify into regulation several best practices for the
conduct and presentation of BCA. In addition, the EPA would require
that a reasoned explanation be provided for any departures from best
practices in the BCA, including a discussion of the likely effect of
the departures on the results of the BCA.
The proposed requirements itemized in the following subsections are
among the best practices outlined in existing peer-reviewed OMB and EPA
guidance documents developed in response to longstanding presidential
orders discussed above: OMB's Circular A-4 (2003) and its associated
guidance (2010, 2011a, 2011b),\20\ EPA's Guidelines for Preparing
Economic Analyses (2010). These guidance documents are grounded in the
economics literature pertaining to the conduct of BCA. Benefit-cost
analysis as a discipline is a branch of applied microeconomic welfare
economics and is summarized in numerous textbooks
[[Page 35618]]
such as Boardman et al. (2018), Farrow (2018), Brent (2006), Mishan and
Quah (2007), and Hanley and Spash (1996).\21\ This discipline is
applied routinely to environmental economics issues and the theory of
BCA and its application can be found in standard environmental economic
textbooks such as Phaneuf and Requate (2016) and Perman et al.
(2012).\22\ Specific lists of best practices and guidance for
practitioners can also be found in articles by Robinson and Hammit
(2016), Sunstein (2014), Farrow (2013), Farrow and Viscusi (2011),
Krutilla (2005), and notably in an article on the principles and
standards by Nobel laureate Kenneth Arrow and a number of prominent
economists (Arrow et al., 1996).\23\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\20\ Office of Management and Budget, U.S., 2003. Circular A-4:
Regulatory Analysis. Office of Management and Budget, U.S., 2010.
Agency Checklist: Regulatory Impact Analysis. Office of Management
and Budget, U.S., 2011a. Circular A-4, ``Regulatory Analysis''
Frequently Asked Questions (FAQs). Office of Management and Budget,
U.S., 2011b. Circular A-4, ``Regulatory Impact Analysis: A Primer''.
\21\ Farrow, S. ed., 2018. Teaching Benefit-Cost Analysis: Tools
of the Trade. Edward Elgar Publishing. Brent, R.J. ed., 2004.
Applied Cost-Benefit Analysis. Edward Elgar Publishing. Mishan, E.J.
and Quah, E., 2007. Cost-benefit analysis. Routledge. Hanley, N. and
Spash, C., 1996. Cost benefit analysis and the environment.
\22\ Phaneuf, D.J. and Requate, T., 2016. A course in
environmental economics: Theory, policy, and practice. Cambridge
University Press. Perman, R., Ma, Y., McGilvray, J. and Common, M.,
2003. Natural resource and environmental economics. Pearson
Education. Krutilla, K., 2005. Using the Kaldor[hyphen]Hicks tableau
format for cost-benefit analysis and policy evaluation. Journal of
Policy Analysis and Management: The Journal of the Association for
Public Policy Analysis and Management, 24(4), pp.864-875.
\23\ Robinson, L.A. and Hammitt, J.K., 2013. Skills of the
trade: Valuing health risk reductions in benefit-cost analysis.
Journal of Benefit-Cost Analysis, 4(1), pp.107-130. Sunstein, C.R.,
2014. The real world of cost-benefit analysis: Thirty-six questions
(and almost as many answers). Columbia Law Review, pp.167-211.
Farrow, S., 2013. How (not) to lie with benefit-cost analysis. The
Economists' Voice, 10(1), pp.45-50. Farrow, S. and Viscusi, W.K.,
2011. Towards principles and standards for the benefit-cost analysis
of safety. Journal of Benefit-Cost Analysis, 2(3), pp.1-25.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Since best practices for the conduct of BCA inherently require that
the inputs to analysis reflect the best available information,\24\ the
EPA is also taking the opportunity in this proposal to require that the
EPA follow certain best practices regarding the incorporation of
information as an input to BCA for significant CAA regulations. In
particular, risk assessments often provide key inputs to the
development of EPA's health benefit estimates in a BCA, and several
commenters recommended that additional consistency and transparency be
applied in the assessment of risks leading to the estimation of
benefits. Through this rulemaking, the EPA proposes requirements to
ensure the consistent and transparent use of risk assessments in BCA of
CAA regulations. These proposed requirements include elements that are
responsive to recommendations from the National Academies of Sciences,
Engineering and Medicine (National Academies) and EPA's Science
Advisory Board (SAB) to improve the utility of risk assessment for use
in BCAs for CAA regulations. This proposal is also consistent with the
2007 OMB and OSTP Updated Principles for Risk Analysis,\25\ which also
builds off of the National Academies and SAB recommendations as well as
EPA's Risk Characterization Handbook.\26\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\24\ See EPA, Guidelines for Ensuring and Maximizing the
Quality, Objectivity, Utility and Integrity of Information
Disseminated by the Environmental Protection Agency (https://www.epa.gov/sites/production/files/2019-08/documents/epa-info-quality-guidelines_1.pdf).
\25\ https://www.whitehouse.gov/sites/whitehouse.gov/files/omb/memoranda/2007/m07-24.pdf.
\26\ https://www.epa.gov/risk/risk-characterization-handbook
(EPA 100-B-00-002, December 2000).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Key elements of a Benefit-Cost Analysis. The key elements of a
rigorous regulatory BCA include: (1) A statement of need; (2) an
examination of regulatory options; and (3) to the extent feasible, an
assessment of all benefits and costs of these regulatory options
relative to the baseline (no action) scenario.
It will not always be possible to express in monetary units all of
the important benefits and costs. When it is not, the most efficient
alternative will not necessarily be the one with the largest quantified
and monetized net-benefit estimate. In such cases, EPA will exercise
its subject matter expertise in determining how important the non-
quantified benefits or costs may be in the context of the overall
analysis. Even when a benefit or cost cannot be expressed in monetary
units, EPA will try to measure it in terms of its physical units. If it
is not possible to measure the physical units, EPA will describe
material benefits or costs qualitatively.
Statement of Need. Each regulatory BCA should include a statement
of need that provides (1) a clear description of the problem being
addressed, (2) the reasons for and significance of any failure of
private markets or public institutions causing this problem, and (3)
the compelling need for federal government intervention in the market
to correct the problem. This statement sets the stage for the
subsequent analysis of benefits and costs and allows one to judge
whether the problem is being adequately addressed by the policy.
Additional discussion of a thorough regulatory statement of need can be
found in OMB (1993, B. Introduction, The Need for Federal Regulatory
Action) and EPA (2010, Chapter 3).
Regulatory Options. The BCA must analyze the benefits and costs of
regulatory options, or other notable deviations from the proposed or
finalized option. Where there is a continuum of options (such as
options that vary in stringency), the BCA must analyze at least three
options which accomplish the stated objectives of the Clean Air Act
(unless the BCA explains the rationale for analyzing fewer than three
options, as further described below) and must explain why they were
selected: The proposed or finalized option; a more stringent option
that achieves additional benefits (and presumably costs more) beyond
those realized by the proposed or finalized option; and a less
stringent option that costs less (and presumably generates fewer
benefits) than the proposed or finalized option. Even when a continuum
of options is not applicable, an analysis of regulatory options
provides an opportunity to analyze a variety of parameters including
different compliance dates, enforcement methods, standards by size or
location of facilities, and regulatory designs (e.g., performance vs.
technology standards). If fewer than three options are analyzed, or if
there is a continuum of options and the options analyzed do not include
at least one more stringent (or otherwise more costly) and one less
stringent (or otherwise less costly) option than the proposed or
finalized option, then the BCA must explain why it is not appropriate
to consider more alternatives. For further discussion, see OMB Circular
A-4, E. Identifying and Measuring Benefits and Costs, General Issues,
3. Evaluation of Alternatives.
Baseline. The baseline in a BCA serves as a basis of comparison
with the regulatory options considered. It is the best assessment of
the way the world would look absent the regulatory action. The choice
of a baseline requires consideration of a wide range of potential
factors, including exogenous changes in the economy that may affect
relevant benefits and costs (e.g., changes over time in demographics,
economic activity, consumer preferences, and technology); impacts of
regulations that have been promulgated by the agency or other
government entities; and the degree of compliance by regulated entities
with other regulations. Accounting for other existing regulations in
the baseline is especially important in order to avoid double counting
of the incremental benefits and costs from other existing regulatory
actions affecting the same environmental condition (e.g., ambient air
quality). When the EPA determines that it is appropriate to consider
more than one baseline (e.g., one that
[[Page 35619]]
accounts for another EPA regulation being developed at the same time
that would affect the same environmental condition), the BCA must
provide a reasoned explanation for the baselines used in sensitivity
analyses and must identify the key uncertainties in the forecast(s).
These proposed requirements for developing a baseline are consistent
with best practices as outlined in OMB's Circular A-4 (1993) and EPA's
Guidelines (2010).
Measuring Benefits and Costs. A BCA evaluates the favorable effects
of a policy action and the opportunity costs associated with the
action. It addresses the question of whether the benefits from the
policy action are sufficient for those who gain to theoretically
compensate those burdened such that everyone would be at least as well
off as before the policy. In other words, many regulations can be
thought of as a requirement to divert resources from activities with a
higher net return in private markets alone to those with a higher net
return when all impacts are counted, thus the calculation of net
benefits (benefits minus costs) helps ascertain the economic efficiency
of a regulation.
In keeping with best practices, the appropriate measures of
benefits and costs to use in a regulatory BCA are social benefits and
social costs. When assessing a regulation, the social benefits are the
society-wide positive changes in well-being, and social costs are the
society-wide opportunities foregone, or reductions in well-being.
Willingness to pay (WTP) is the correct measure of these changes in
BCA.\27\ WTP provides a full accounting of an individual's preference
for an outcome by identifying what the individual would give up to
attain that outcome. WTP is measured in monetary terms to allow a
comparison of benefits to costs in the net benefit calculation. If the
BCA departs from these best practices (e.g., where WTP is hard to
measure), it must include a robust explanation for doing so. For
further discussion, see OMB Circular A-4, E. Identifying and Measuring
Benefits and Costs, General Issues, 2. Developing a Baseline and
Guidelines (2010/2014), Chapter 5. Baseline.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\27\ Willingness to pay means the largest amount of money that
an individual or group would pay to receive the benefits (or avoid
the damages) resulting from a policy change, without being made
worse off. The principle of WTP captures the notion of opportunity
cost by measuring what individuals are willing to forgo to enjoy a
particular benefit. In general, economists tend to view WTP as the
most appropriate measure of opportunity cost, but an individual's
``willingness-to-accept'' (WTA) compensation for not receiving the
improvement can also provide a valid measure of opportunity cost.
WTP is generally considered to be more readily measurable. Market
prices provide rich data for estimating benefits and costs based on
WTP if the goods and services affected by the regulation are traded
in well-functioning competitive markets. See Hanley and Spash
(1993), Freeman (2003), Just et al. (2005), and Appendix A of the
Guidelines (2010/14).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
While based on the same underlying conceptual framework, social
benefits and social costs are often evaluated separately due to
practical considerations. The social benefits of reduced pollution are
often attributable to changes in outcomes not exchanged in markets,
such as improvements in public health or ecosystems. In contrast, the
social costs generally are measured through changes in outcomes that
are exchanged in markets. As a result, different techniques are used to
estimate social benefits and social costs however, in both cases the
goal is to estimate measures of WTP to provide consistency.
Methods for Estimating Benefits and Costs. Although the most
appropriate methods for estimating social costs and social benefits can
often be regulation-specific, there are best practices for selecting
these methods. The EPA proposes that all BCAs will rely on such best
practices and will provide reasoned explanations for methods selected.
These best practices include the use of a framework that is appropriate
for the characteristics of the regulation being evaluated. As discussed
in OMB Circular A-4, a good regulatory analysis cannot be developed
according to a formula. Conducting high-quality analysis requires
competent professional judgment. Different regulations may call for
different emphases in the analysis, depending on the nature and
complexity of the regulatory issues and the sensitivity of the benefit
and cost estimates to the key assumptions. For example, the extent to
which compliance cost is a sufficient measure of social costs will
depend on whether a regulation is expected to result in changes in
prices and quantities within and across markets. Other considerations
when selecting an estimation method include the ability of an
estimation approach to capture certain types of costs, to adequately
reflect the geographic and sectoral detail and scope of the rule, and
to reflect how costs may change over time, among other considerations.
During the estimation process, analysts must consider how social
cost and benefit endpoints may be affected by behaviors in the baseline
and potential behavioral changes from the policy. For example, three
broad frameworks for estimating social cost--compliance cost, partial
equilibrium, and general equilibrium--offer different scopes in terms
of the degree to which behavioral response and other market
imperfections are included. In general, analysts can improve the
accuracy of cost estimates by reducing known biases due to the omission
of potentially important behavioral responses or missing opportunity
costs. However, adopting more complex approaches can reduce the
precision of estimates due to data and modeling limitations. A
compliance cost approach typically identifies the private expenditures
associated with compliance in the regulated sector(s). Compliance cost
estimates typically exclude behavioral responses outside of the choice
of compliance activity and may, therefore, not capture some opportunity
costs associated with regulations. However, with adequate data, this
approach can generate highly detailed and relatively precise
information on compliance options and costs, reflecting the
heterogeneity of regulated entities. This can provide a reasonable
estimate of the social cost of a regulation when changes in the
regulated sector's outputs and input mix are expected to be minimal and
no large market effects are anticipated. A partial equilibrium analysis
captures supply and demand responses in the regulated sector due to
compliance activities and may, therefore, provide a more complete
estimate of compliance costs in addition to any lost profits and
consumer welfare due to reductions in output. In other words,
behavioral responses can have important impacts on both the size and
distribution of benefits and costs, and therefore can provide a fuller
picture of the social impact of a particular regulation. Partial
equilibrium analyses may be extended to consider a small number of
related sectors in addition to those directly regulated (e.g., upstream
markets that supply intermediate goods to the regulated sector, or
markets for substitute or complementary products). A partial
equilibrium approach is preferred for estimating social cost when the
regulation will result in appreciable behavioral change, but the
effects will be confined primarily to a single market or a small number
of markets. When broader economy-wide impacts are expected as a result
of the regulation, a partial equilibrium approach will miss these
effects. In this case, a general equilibrium approach may be more
appropriate to more adequately estimate social cost.
A general equilibrium approach, which captures linkages between
markets across the entire economy, is most likely to add value when
both relevant relationships among sectors
[[Page 35620]]
and pre-existing market distortions are expected to be significant.
Market distortions are factors such as pre-existing taxes,
externalities, regulations, or imperfectly competitive markets that
move consumers or firms away from what would occur in the absence of
such distortions. For example, when an environmental regulation affects
the real wage such that individuals opt to work fewer hours, it can
exacerbate pre-existing inefficiencies in the labor market due to
taxes, regulatory barriers, or other market imperfections. This
represents a welfare cost not captured by compliance cost estimates.
The impacts of a regulation also may interact with pre-existing
distortions in other markets, which may cause additional impacts on
welfare either positively or negatively. In cases such as these, a
general equilibrium approach may be capable of identifying how the
costs of complying with a regulation flow through the economy, such as
through changes in substitution among factors of production, trade
patterns, and demand for goods and services. These effects are
partially or wholly missed by compliance cost and partial equilibrium
approaches. For further discussion, see Guidelines (2010/2014), Chapter
8, Analyzing Costs, 8.1. The Economics of Social Cost.
The estimated social benefits reported in a BCA should link
regulatory requirements to the value that individuals place on the
beneficial outcomes,\28\ or benefit endpoints, that can be meaningfully
expected as a result of those requirements. Benefits assessment is,
therefore, typically a multi-step process. The starting point is
identifying the changes in environmental contaminants or stressors that
are likely to result from policy options relative to the baseline.
These changes are often characterized through air quality modeling. The
next step is to identify the benefit endpoints that may be affected by
changes in environmental quality, such as human health improvements,
ecological improvements, aesthetic improvements, and reduced materials
damages. The EPA recognizes that the strength of scientific evidence
for different health or environmental endpoints varies, and that
strength of scientific evidence should be strongest when the benefits
are estimated. As further discussed in OMB's M 19-15, this concept is
referred to as ``fitness for purpose,'' whereby information anticipated
to have a higher impact must be held to higher standards of
quality.\29\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\28\ As a practical matter, the value of any adverse public
health or welfare outcomes (sometimes referred to as
``disbenefits'') resulting from the regulatory requirements are
usually also included on the benefits side of the ledger in
regulatory BCAs, although it is theoretically appropriate to include
them on the cost side. Such adverse outcomes could include adverse
economic, health, safety, or environmental consequences that occur
due to a rule (e.g., adverse safety impacts from vehicle emission
standards) and are not already accounted for in the direct cost of
the rule.
\29\ OMB's M-19-15 refers back to OMB's 2002 Guidelines, which
characterize a subset of agency information as ``influential
scientific, financial, or statistical information'' that is held to
higher quality standards. This is scientific, financial, or
statistical information that ``the agency can reasonably determine .
. . will have or does have a clear and substantial impact on
important public policies or important private sector decisions.''
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The EPA proposes to select the endpoints for which the scientific
evidence indicates there is (a) a clear causal or likely causal
relationship between pollutant exposure and effect, and subsequently,
(b) an anticipated change in that effect in response to changes in
environmental quality or exposures is expected as a result of the
regulation under analysis. EPA takes comment on an alternative,
approach that would select all endpoints for which there is a positive
WTP conditional on the available scientific literature.
Once benefit endpoints are identified, decisions must be made about
whether and how to quantify changes in each endpoint. From among the
endpoints identified above, the EPA proposes to quantify effects for
endpoints which scientific evidence is robust enough to support such
quantification. If the Agency determines that some benefits should be
discussed only qualitatively, for example, due to limited scientific
evidence or limited resources for developing concentration response
functions, the Agency must provide a reasoned explanation for that
decision. Additional information on choosing and quantifying health
endpoints is described further below.
Quantification is then followed by valuation of these endpoints
when data and methods allow. There are well-defined economic principles
and well-established economic methods for valuation as detailed in OMB
and Agency guidance, including Circular A-4 and the EPA Guidelines for
Preparing Economic Analyses. Finally, the valued endpoints should be
aggregated to the extent possible and supported by scientific and
economic practice to provide the basis for characterizing the benefits
of each policy option.
In some instances, it may be possible to value bundles of
attributes or endpoints using reduced-form techniques, such as the
hedonic property method. Care and professional judgment are necessary
in determining the appropriateness of bundling of several endpoints
versus modeling separate endpoints. Even if bundling is thought to be
appropriate, it can be useful to think through the multi-step process
above conceptually to: (a) Assess whether there are benefit endpoints
not reflected in the reduced form valuation estimate that should be
included through additional analysis, or (b) compare the magnitudes of
multi-step and reduced-form, revealed-preference benefits estimates so
that each can provide a check on the reliability of the other.
In summary, the EPA proposes that, to the extent supported by the
scientific criteria, as discussed above, as well as practicable in a
given rulemaking, (1) BCAs will quantify all benefits; (2) BCAs will
monetize all the benefits by following well-defined economic principles
using well-established economic methods; and (3) BCAs will
qualitatively characterize benefits that cannot be quantified or
monetized. In addition, the EPA proposes that the Agency must explain
any departure from the best practices for the BCA described in Circular
A-4; this includes discussing the likely effect of the departures on
the size of the benefits estimate. More discussion of these best
practices and estimation methods is provided in Circular A-4 and EPA's
Guidelines for Preparing Economic Analyses, and the literature cited
therein.
Quantifying Health Endpoints in a BCA: Decisions about whether and
which changes in the health endpoints should be quantified should be
informed by the Agency's evaluation of the relevant scientific
literature establishing a link between chemical exposure and health
endpoint and the nature of the concentration-response function (i.e.,
the amount of change in the frequency or severity of the health
endpoint expected as the distribution of air quality changes.) In its
evaluation, the Agency should explicitly state when scientific
judgments or assumptions were used and their effect on the
concentration-response function, if known. The Agency would select
among concentration-response relationships from studies that satisfied
the following minimum standards: (1) The study was externally and
independently peer-reviewed consistent with Federal guidance; (2) the
pollutant analyzed in the study matches the pollutant of interest in
the regulation; (3) concentration-response functions must be
parameterized from scientifically robust studies; and (4) when an
epidemiological study is used, further
[[Page 35621]]
criteria include: (a) It must assess the influence of confounders; (b)
the study location must be appropriately matched to the analysis; and
(c) the study population characteristics must be sufficiently similar
to those of the analysis. When multiple studies satisfy these criteria,
the EPA would characterize multiple concentration-response functions
reflecting the full set of studies as a means of providing a broader
representation of the effects estimate, including high quality studies
that do not find a significant concentration-response relationship.
When selecting multiple concentration-response functions, the
Agency would quantify risks using separate concentration-response
relationship and, if appropriate, pool, or combine, the results (e.g.
in a meta-analysis) as means of providing a broader representation of
the effects estimate. EPA proposes to require that decisions about the
choice of the number of alternative concentration-response functions
quantified for each endpoint be based on the extent to which it is
technically feasible to quantify alternative concentration-response
relationships given the available data and resources. Decisions should
also consider the sensitivity of net benefits to the choice of
concentration-response function. EPA proposes to present results in a
manner that promotes transparency in the assessment process by
selecting and clearly identifying concentration-response functions with
the strongest scientific evidence, as well as evidence necessary to
demonstrate the sensitivity of the choice of the concentration-response
function on the magnitude and the uncertainty associated with air
pollution-attributable effects.
Once the Agency has identified the concentration-response functions
to be used for quantifying the selected health endpoints, the Agency
proposes that the BCA, or related technical support document, must
characterize:
The variability in the concentration-response functions
across studies and models, including plausible alternatives;
the assumptions, defaults, and uncertainties, their
rationale, and their influence on the resulting estimates;
the extent to which scientific literature suggests that
the nature of the effect may vary across demographic or health
characteristics;
the potential variability of the concentration-response
function over the range in concentrations of interest for the given
policy;
the influence of potential confounders on the reported
risk coefficient;
the likelihood that the parameters of the concentration-
response differ based on geographic location; and
attributes that affect the suitability of the study or
model for informing a risk assessment, including the age of the air
quality data, and the generalizability of the study population.
In cases where existing Agency documents (e.g., an Integrated
Science Assessment for criteria pollutants) provide the causal
analysis, concentration-response analysis, or the factors indicated
above to be included in the BCA, the BCA may reference this synthesis.
Evidence from epidemiologic, experimental, and controlled human
exposure studies may suggest that certain demographic subgroups are
subject to risks that differ from the general population; in these
instances, it may be appropriate to select concentration-response
relationships that quantify risks among these specific subgroups.
BCA requires a comparison of expected costs and expected benefits,
so BCA for CAA regulations must include the determination of expected
benefits. When feasible, a probability distribution of risk is
appropriate to use when determining the expected benefits for CAA
regulations. When it is infeasible to estimate a probability
distribution, the EPA proposes that measures of the central tendency of
risk be used. Upper-bound risk estimates must not be used unless they
are presented in conjunction with lower bound and central tendency
estimates.
Uncertainty Analysis. For various reasons, including the reason
that the future is unpredictable, the benefits and costs of future
regulatory options are not known with certainty. BCAs should identify
uncertainties underlying the estimation of both benefits and costs and,
to the extent feasible, quantitatively analyze those that are most
influential. Specifically, the EPA must characterize, preferably
quantitatively, sources of uncertainty in the assessment of costs,
changes in air quality, assessment of likely changes in health and
welfare endpoints, and the valuation of those changes. The EPA must
also present benefit and cost estimates in ways that convey their
uncertainty. The BCA must include a reasoned explanation for the scope
of the uncertainty analysis and must specify specific quantitative or
qualitative methods chosen to analyze uncertainties. Quantitative
uncertainty analyses may consider both statistical and model
uncertainty where the data are sufficient to do so. Furthermore, where
data are sufficient to do so, the BCA must consider sources of
uncertainty independently as well as jointly. The BCA should also
discuss the extent to which qualitatively assessed costs or benefits
are characterized by uncertainty.
Where probability distributions for relevant input assumptions are
available, characterize significant sources of uncertainty in the
assessment, and can be feasibly and credibly combined, the EPA proposes
that BCAs characterize how the probability distributions of the
relevant input assumption uncertainty would impact the resulting
distribution of benefit and cost estimates. The EPA should report
probability distributions for each health benefit whenever feasible. In
addition to characterizing these distributions of outcomes, it is
useful to emphasize summary statistics or figures that can be readily
understood and compared to achieve the broadest public understanding of
the findings. If this proposed rulemaking is adopted, there will be
instances when calculating expected values is not practicable due to
data or other limitations. In such instances, the EPA would strive to
present a plausible range of benefits and costs. Additional discussion
of these best practices related to uncertainty analysis is provided in
OMB's Circular A-4, Treatment of Uncertainty, and throughout EPA's
Guidelines for Preparing Economic Analyses Guidelines.
Principle of Transparency. The EPA proposes that BCA of significant
CAA regulations include, at a minimum, a detailed and clear explanation
of:
The overall results of the BCA. The EPA proposes that the
benefits, costs, and net benefits of each regulatory option evaluated
in the BCA be presented in a manner designed to be objective,
comprehensive, and easily understood by the public.
How the benefits and costs were estimated, including the
assumptions made for the analysis. BCAs must include a clear
explanation of the models, data, and assumptions used to estimate
benefits and costs, and the evaluation and selection process for these
analytical decisions. This explanation would also include an
explanation of procedures used to select among input parameters for the
benefit and cost models. Such an explanation could include methods used
to quantify risk and to model the fate and transport of pollutants.
All non-monetized and non-quantified benefits and costs of
the action. BCAs must provide available
[[Page 35622]]
evidence on all non-monetized and non-quantified benefits and costs,
including why they are not being monetized or quantified and what the
potential impact of those benefits and costs might be on the overall
results of the BCA.
The primary sources and potential effects of uncertainty.
The BCA must present the results of the assessment of the sources of
uncertainty that are likely to have a substantial effect on the
results. Any data and models used to analyze uncertainty must be fully
identified, and the quality of the available data must be discussed.
Finally, to the extent permitted by law, the EPA proposes to make
the information (including data and models) that was used in the
development of the BCA publicly available. If the data and models are
proprietary, the EPA proposes to make the underlying inputs and
assumptions used, primary equations, and methodologies available to the
extent permitted by law, while continuing to protect information
claimed as confidential business information (CBI), personally
identifiable information (PII), and other privileged, non-exempt
information.
Additional discussion of these best practices related to
transparency is provided in OMB's Circular A-4, Transparency and
Reproducibility of Results, and throughout EPA's Guidelines (2010).
C. Requirement for Additional Presentations of BCA Results in
Rulemakings
One theme raised by many commenters on the ANPRM was that the EPA
does not clearly distinguish benefit categories in its regulatory
documents. These commenters stated that EPA's BCAs generally present
benefits as an aggregate total, and that insufficient effort is made to
clearly distinguish between the public health and welfare benefits
attributable to the specific pollution reductions or other
environmental quality goals that are targeted by the specific statutory
provision or provisions that authorize the regulation, and other
welfare effects of the regulation that are not the primary objective of
the statutory provision or provisions. For example, some commenters
pointed to reports that show that for regulations for which a BCA is
available, the majority of the monetized benefits for CAA regulations
were attributable to reductions in fine particulate matter
(PM2.5) even though the regulation did not target
PM2.5. This issue did not arise with respect to costs in the
public comments received on the ANPRM.
While BCA requires a comparison of total social benefits and total
social costs, commenters state that this comparison does not
transparently communicate and may also create public confusion about
the nature and scope of the statutory authority that provides the basis
for the regulation, if a disproportionate share of social benefits
arise from changes in environmental and other outcomes unrelated or
secondary to the statutory objective of the regulation. While the
Agency did not receive public comments on the presentation of costs,
this principle of transparency would also apply to considerations of
cost as contemplated by the statute when in pursuit those environmental
benefits.
Following the principle of transparency, the EPA agrees with
commenters that when presenting the results of a BCA, it is important
to clearly distinguish between the social benefits attributable to the
specific pollution reductions or other environmental quality goals that
are targeted by the statutory provisions that give rise to the
regulation, and other welfare effects. The disaggregation of welfare
effects will be important to ensure that the BCA may provide, to the
maximum extent feasible, transparency in decision making. These other
welfare effects could include both favorable and adverse impacts on
societal welfare. Analogous to how a regulation's interactions with
existing imperfections or distortions in other markets (e.g., due to
pre-existing taxes) could lead to additional social costs, a regulation
could ameliorate or exacerbate other pre-existing externalities. For
example, more stringent vehicle emissions standards could affect
upstream refinery emissions or reduce the marginal cost of driving due
to greater fuel efficiency and could lead to an increase in vehicle
miles traveled that affects road safety, congestion, and other
transport-related externalities.
Other welfare effects could also occur as a direct or indirect
result of the compliance approaches used by regulated entities. For
example, changes in other environmental contaminants may arise from the
regulated sources. Likewise, the use of an abatement technology that
reduces the emissions of HAPs into one medium (e.g., air) may change
the emissions of another pollutant into the same medium (e.g., coming
out of the same smokestack) or cause changes in emissions of pollutants
into another medium (e.g., water) by the regulated sources. Changes in
other environmental contaminants may also occur as a result of market
interactions induced by the regulation. For example, a regulation may
cause consumers or firms to substitute away from one commodity towards
another, whose increased production may be associated with changes in
various environmental contaminants or other externalities.
The welfare effects associated with these changes should be
accounted for in a BCA to the extent feasible, as it is the total
willingness to pay for all changes induced by a regulation that
determines their relative importance in evaluating economic efficiency.
Disaggregating benefits into those targeted and ancillary to the
statutory objective of the regulation may cause the EPA to explore
whether there may be more efficient, lawful and defensible, or
otherwise appropriate ways of obtaining ancillary benefits, as they may
be the primary target of an alternative regulation that may more
efficiently address such pollutants, through a more flexible regulatory
mechanism, better geographic focus, or other factors. This may be
relevant when certain benefits are the result of changes in pollutants
that the EPA regulates under a different section of the CAA or under
another statute.
Proposed Requirements: EPA proposes to codify into regulation two
presentational requirements for the preamble of all future significant
CAA regulations. First, in order to ensure standardized presentation of
the summary of the BCA results consistent with E.O. 12866 in CAA
rulemakings, the EPA proposes to codify into regulation the requirement
to present a summary in the preamble of the overall BCA results,
including total costs, benefits, and net benefits. Second, to enhance
transparency about the extent to which a rule is achieving its
statutory objectives, the EPA proposes, in addition to a clear
reporting of the overall results of the BCA, an additional presentation
in the preamble of the public health and welfare benefits that pertain
to the specific objective (or objectives, as the case may be) of the
CAA provision or provisions under which the rule is promulgated. This
second presentation would include a listing of the benefit categories
arising from the environmental improvement that is targeted by the
relevant statutory provision, or provisions and would report the
monetized value to society of these benefits. If these benefit
categories cannot be monetized, the EPA is proposing that the Agency
must report the quantified estimates of these benefits to the extent
practicable and must provide a qualitative characterization if they
cannot be quantified. Similarly, if the statute directs or allows the
Agency to consider
[[Page 35623]]
costs, the EPA proposes to also provide a disaggregation of all
relevant cost categories to the extent feasible in this section. This
proposed requirement would serve as supplement to the BCA that is
developed and presented according to best practices as outlined in
Section IV.B of this preamble. It does not replace or change any part
of the RIA or the section of the preamble that summarizes the BCA
results consistent with E.O. 12866. As discussed in Section V of this
preamble, the EPA requests comment on alternative ways of increasing
transparency about the extent to which a rule is achieving its
statutory environmental objective. Finally, the EPA proposes that the
presentational requirements described above be provided in the same
section of the preamble of future CAA significant rulemakings.
V. Additional Considerations and Requests for Comment
A. Specifying How BCA Results Should Inform Regulatory Decisions
The EPA is proposing that the Agency undertake a BCA for
significant regulations but is not proposing to specify how or whether
the results of the BCA should inform significant CAA regulatory
decisions. For example, the EPA is not proposing to mandate that a
significant CAA regulation be promulgated only when the benefits of the
intended action justify its costs. Such a mandate would not be
appropriate, for example, for regulations promulgated under provisions
of the CAA that have been read by the courts to prohibit the
consideration of costs in decision-making. For example, ``[t]he text of
Sec. 109(b), interpreted in its statutory and historical context and
with appreciation for its importance to the CAA as a whole,
unambiguously bars cost considerations from the NAAQS-setting
process.'' Am. Trucking Ass'ns, 531 U.S. at 471. Thus, such a mandate
would be improper for the NAAQS-setting process. There are other CAA
provisions, however, that explicitly require the EPA to take costs into
consideration in deciding how or whether to regulate. In addition,
several provisions do not explicitly use the word ``cost'' but use
terminology that implicitly requires or permits cost consideration. For
example, terms such as ``reasonable,'' ``appropriate,'' ``necessary,''
or ``feasible'' have been interpreted as allowing for or even requiring
the consideration of cost in decision making. Accordingly, when
regulating pursuant to a CAA provision that either explicitly or
implicitly requires or permits consideration of cost, it may be
appropriate, depending on the statutory provision at issue, to consider
whether the benefits of a regulation justify the costs in deciding
whether or how to regulate.
In this proposal, the EPA solicits comment on how the Agency could
take into consideration the results of a BCA in future rulemakings
under specific provisions of the CAA. The EPA also solicits comment on
approaches for how the results of the BCA could be weighed in future
CAA regulatory decisions. For example, the EPA solicits comment on
whether and under what circumstances the EPA could or should determine
that a future significant CAA regulation be promulgated only when the
benefits of the intended action justify its costs. The EPA also
solicits comment on whether and under what circumstances the EPA could
determine that a future significant CAA regulation be promulgated only
when monetized benefits exceed the costs of the action.
B. Other Areas of Solicitation for Public Comment
Applicability. EPA is requesting comment on whether this rulemaking
should apply only to the subset of CAA significant regulations that are
determined to be economically significant, which the EPA could define,
consistent with E.O. 12866 Section 3(f)(1) and OMB Circular A-4, as
those that are likely to have an effect on the economy (benefits, costs
or transfers) of $100 million or more in any one year (that is, a
consecutive twelve-month period) or adversely affect in a material way
the economy, a sector of the economy, productivity, competition, jobs,
the environment, public health or safety, or State, local, or tribal
governments or communities. These economically significant regulations
are the same set of regulations for which E.O. 12866 requires the
preparation of a BCA. The EPA also requests comment on whether the
threshold of $100 million in benefits and/or costs in any given year
should be adjusted for inflation going forward, and, if so, whether
such adjustments should be made assuming a base year of 1995 (as is
done with the $100 million expenditure threshold set forth in the
Unfunded Mandates Reform Act).The EPA is requesting comment on whether
certain elements of the proposed action should consider resource
constraints when being implemented for CAA significant regulations,
under the reasonable proposition embedded in E.O. 12866 that the
intensity of the resources dedicated to an analysis should be
coordinated and consistent with the level of impact of a decision.
Best Practices for the Development of BCA. The EPA is requesting
comment whether it is appropriate to codify best practices for the
development of BCA in this rulemaking and, if so, whether specific
additional best practices should also be so codified. For example, the
EPA solicits comment on whether this rulemaking should specify best
practices related to assumptions about technological change and/or
learning effects in BCA. The EPA further solicits comment as to whether
any additional proposed requirements for BCAs would improve BCA
consistency. EPA solicits comments as to whether non-domestic benefits
and costs of regulations, when examined, should be reported separately
from domestic benefits and costs of such regulations, just as this
proposed rulemaking would provide for a separate presentation of
benefits limited to those targeted by the relevant statutory provision
or provisions.
The EPA is requesting comment as to whether requirements related to
risk assessments used in BCAs should be applied more broadly than as
described in the proposed rulemaking and, in particular, whether such
requirements should apply to all risk assessments used in CAA
significant rulemakings. For example, should EPA codify into regulation
the proposed selection criteria for selecting among studies
characterizing concentration-response relationships and the proposed
requirement for synthesizing evidence across the literature? The EPA
also solicits comment on whether to impose additional requirements for
risk assessments. For example, should the EPA impose requirements for
best practices related to any weight-of-evidence (WOE) frameworks that
the Agency uses in the developments of CAA significant rulemakings?
Should EPA impose additional requirements to ensure consistency and
transparency in the assessment of bias and uncertainty in risk analyses
(e.g., requirements relating to the use of quantitative bias analysis,
or requirements intended for consistency purposes such as requirements
relating to the use of probabilistic risk analysis for reducing
uncertainty in risk analysis)? The EPA also solicits comments on
whether additional requirements within the study selection criteria are
necessary to ensure a high-quality and appropriately reliable
characterization of air quality and risk.
Additional Presentational Requirements to Increase Transparency.
EPA requests comment on alternative approaches to increasing
transparency about the extent to which a rule is achieving its
statutory objectives. In
[[Page 35624]]
particular, EPA solicits comment on whether, instead of, or in addition
to, the presentational requirements proposed in Section IV.C of this
preamble, the EPA should require a detailed disaggregation of both
benefit and cost categories within the table that summarizes the
overall results of the BCA in the preamble of future significant CAA
rulemakings. The goal of this disaggregation would be to clarify what
public health and welfare benefits pertain to the specific statutory
objective, or objectives, of the CAA provision, or provisions, under
which the rule is promulgated, but would allow the reader to see this
information in the same location as the estimates of all the other
welfare effects, both positive and negative, resulting from the
regulation. In addition, the EPA solicits comment on whether the EPA
should require a separate presentation of all factors (e.g., particular
benefit or cost categories, or other impacts) that are specifically
listed as factors that the Administrator must consider in making a
regulatory decision pursuant to the statutory provision(s) under which
the regulation is being promulgated. This presentation would include a
presentation of quantitative results for those factors that have been
quantitatively assessed, and a qualitative discussion of any factors
that were not quantified.
Retrospective Analysis. EPA requests comment on whether EPA should
include a requirement for conducting retrospective analysis of
significant CAA rulemakings. As discussed in the ANPRM, many previous
administrations have periodically undertaken programs of retrospective
review or issued executive orders urging agencies to reassess existing
regulations and to eliminate, modify, or strengthen those regulations
that have become outmoded in light of changed circumstances. But for
the most part retrospective review has not become institutionalized
practice as has prospective review (such as ex ante benefit-cost
analysis conducted under Executive Order 12866) within EPA. The EPA
received many comment letters on the ANPRM voicing support for
increased retrospective review of Agency rules or programs to be able
to evaluate the effectiveness of regulations and to design future
improvements to increase efficiency. In this NPRM the EPA requests more
specific comments on this issue. In particular, what form should a
requirement take in the case of CAA regulations? For example, should
the requirement pertain to analysis of an individual rule or a review
of the cumulative burden of a set of rules regulating the same or
related entities? Should it be applicable to all parts of CAA or just
some provisions? What are the advantages and disadvantages of such a
requirement? How can the Agency overcome the challenges conducting
retrospective analysis in cases where the EPA's ability to collect
information about the costs of compliance is limited or otherwise
influenced by other statutes?
Sequence of Rules in Benefit-Cost Analysis. EPA seeks comment on
how sequencing of rules might affect the estimation of benefits and
costs.
Definitions. The EPA is requesting comment on whether there are
additional terms that it should define to increase consistency and
transparency in the development of BCA to support CAA rulemaking
actions.
Making Information Public. The EPA requests comments as to whether
the proposed criteria regarding data, assumptions, and study selection
reflect the Agency's commitment to be consistent and transparent. The
EPA solicits comment on whether this rule should allow the Agency to
use models offered by a third party only where the third party makes
its models and assumptions publicly available (or allows the EPA to do
so) to the extent permitted by law.
VI. References
The following is a listing of the documents that are specifically
referenced in this document. The docket includes these documents and
other information considered by the EPA, including documents referenced
within the documents that are included in the docket, even if a
referenced document is not physically located in the docket. For
assistance in locating these other documents, please consult the person
listed under the For Further Information Contact section above.
1. U.S. EPA (U.S. Environmental Protection Agency). Increasing
Consistency and Transparency in Considering Costs and Benefits in
the Rulemaking Process; Advance notice of proposed rulemaking. (83
FR 27524, June 13, 2018).
2. OMB (Office of Management and Budget). (1996). Economic Analysis
of Federal Regulations Under Executive Order 12866.
3. OMB (Office of Management and Budget). (2003). Circular A-4,
``Regulatory Analysis.''
4. U.S. EPA (U.S. Environmental Protection Agency). (2010).
Guidelines for Preparing Economic Analyses.
5. Arrow, K., M. Cropper, G. Eads, R. Hahn, L. Lave, R. Noll, P.
Portney, M. Russell, R. Schmalensee, V. Smith, and R. Stavins.
1996a. Benefit-Cost Analysis in Environmental, Health, and Safety
Regulation: A Statement of Principles. Washington, DC: American
Enterprise Institute, The Annapolis Center, and Resources for the
Future.
6. Arrow et al. 1996b. Is There a Role for Benefit-Cost Analysis in
Environmental, Health, and Safety Regulation? Science 272: 221-222.
VII. Statutory and Executive Order Reviews
Additional information about these statutes and Executive Orders
can be found at https://www.epa.gov/laws-regulations/laws-and-executive-orders.
A. Executive Order 12866: Regulatory Planning and Review and Executive
Order 13563: Improving Regulation and Regulatory Review
This proposed action is a significant regulatory action that was
submitted to the OMB for review. Any changes made in response to OMB
recommendations have been documented in the docket. The EPA does not
anticipate that this rulemaking will have an economic impact on
regulated entities. This is a rule of agency procedure and practice.
B. Executive Order 13771: Reducing Regulations and Controlling
Regulatory Costs
This proposed action is not expected to be an Executive Order 13771
regulatory action because it relates to ``agency organization,
management or personnel.''
C. Paperwork Reduction Act (PRA)
This proposed action does not contain any information collection
activities and therefore does not impose an information collection
burden under the PRA.
D. Regulatory Flexibility Act (RFA)
I certify that this proposed action would not have a significant
economic impact on a substantial number of small entities under the
RFA. This action would not impose any requirements on small entities.
This action would not regulate any entity outside the federal
government.
E. Unfunded Mandates Reform Act (UMRA)
This proposed action does not contain any unfunded mandate as
described in UMRA, 2 U.S.C. 1531-1538, and does not significantly or
uniquely affect small governments. The action proposed would impose no
enforceable duty on any state, local or tribal governments or the
private sector.
F. Executive Order 13132: Federalism
This proposed action does not have federalism implications. It
would not
[[Page 35625]]
have substantial direct effects on the states, on the relationship
between the national government and the states, or on the distribution
of power and responsibilities among the various levels of government.
G. Executive Order 13175: Consultation and Coordination With Indian
Tribal Governments
This proposed action does not have tribal implications as specified
in Executive Order 13175. Thus, Executive Order 13175 does not apply to
this action.
H. Executive Order 13045: Protection of Children From Environmental
Health Risks and Safety Risks
The EPA interprets Executive Order 13045 as applying only to those
regulatory actions that concern environmental health or safety risks
that the EPA has reason to believe may disproportionately affect
children, per the definition of ``covered regulatory action'' in
section 2-202 of the Executive Order. This proposed action is not
subject to Executive Order 13045 because it does not concern an
environmental health risk or safety risk.
I. Executive Order 13211: Actions Concerning Regulations That
Significantly Affect Energy Supply, Distribution or Use
This proposed action is not a ``significant energy action'' because
it is not likely to have a significant adverse effect on the supply,
distribution or use of energy.
J. National Technology Transfer and Advancement Act (NTTAA)
This rulemaking does not involve technical standards.
K. Executive Order 12898: Federal Actions To Address Environmental
Justice in Minority Populations and Low-Income Populations
The EPA believes that this proposed action is not subject to
Executive Order 12898 (59 FR 7629, February 16, 1994) because it does
not establish an environmental health or safety standard.
List of Subjects in 40 CFR Part 83
Environmental protection, Administrative practice and procedure,
Reporting and recordkeeping requirements.
Andrew Wheeler,
Administrator.
For the reasons set forth in the preamble, EPA is proposing to add
40 CFR part 83 as follows:
PART 83--INCREASING CONSISTENCY AND TRANSPARENCY IN CONSIDERING
BENEFITS AND COSTS IN CLEAN AIR ACT RULEMAKING PROCESS
Sec.
83.1 What definitions apply to this subpart?
83.2 How do the provisions of this subpart apply?
83.3 What requirements apply to EPA's preparations of Benefit-Cost
Analyses (BCAs) under the Clean Air Act?
83.4 What additional requirements apply to EPA's presentation of BCA
results for all significant rules promulgated under the Clean Air
Act?
Authority: 42 U.S.C. 7601(a)(1)
Subpart A--Analysis of Air Regulations
Sec. 83.1 What definitions apply to this subpart?
Baseline means the best assessment of the way the world would look
absent the proposed or finalized action.
Benefit-cost analysis (BCA) means an evaluation of the favorable
effects of a policy action and the opportunity costs, associated with
the action. It addresses the question whether the benefits for those
who gain from the action are sufficient to, in principle, compensate
those burdened such that everyone would be at least as well off as
before the policy. The calculation of net benefits (benefits minus
costs) helps ascertain the economic efficiency of a regulation.
Compliance cost means the private cost that a regulated entity
incurs to comply with a regulation (e.g., installation and operation of
pollution abatement equipment).
Data means the set of recorded factual material commonly accepted
in the scientific community as necessary to validate research findings
in which obvious errors, such as keystroke or coding errors, have been
removed and that is capable of being analyzed by either the original
researcher or an independent party.
Expected value is a measure of the central tendency of a set of
data. It is usually the average or mean of the data. For a variable
with a discrete number of outcomes, the expected value is calculated by
multiplying each of the possible outcomes by the likelihood that each
outcome will occur and then summing all of those values.
Model means a simplification of reality that is constructed to gain
insights into select attributes of a physical, biological, economic, or
social system. A formal representation of the behavior of system
processes, often in mathematical or statistical terms. The basis can
also be physical or conceptual.
Opportunity cost means the value of the next best alternative to a
particular activity or resource.
Publicly available means lawfully available to the general public
from federal, state, or local government records; the internet; widely
distributed media; or disclosures to the general public that are
required to be made by federal, state, or local law.
Regulatory options means, at a minimum:
(1) The proposed or finalized option;
(2) A more stringent option which accomplishes the stated
objectives of the Clean Air Act and that achieves additional benefits
(and presumably costs more) beyond those realized by the proposed or
finalized option; and
(3) A less stringent option which accomplishes the stated
objectives of the Clean Air Act and that costs less (and presumably
generates fewer benefits) than the proposed or finalized option.
Sensitivity Analysis means an analysis that is used to assess how
the final results or other aspects of an analysis change as input
parameters change, particularly when only point estimates of parameters
are available. Typically, a sensitivity analysis measures how a model's
output changes as one of the input parameters change. Joint sensitivity
analysis (varying more than one parameter at a time) is sometimes
useful as well.
Significant regulation means a proposed or final regulation that is
determined to be a ``significant regulatory action'' pursuant to
Section 3(f) E.O. 12866 or is otherwise designated as significant by
the Administrator.
Social benefits, or benefits, means the positive changes in
societal well-being incurred as a result of the regulation or policy
action.
Social costs, or costs, means the sum of all opportunity costs, or
reductions in societal well-being, incurred as a result of the
regulation or policy action.
Sec. 83.2 How do the provisions of this subpart apply?
(a) The provisions of this subpart apply to benefit-cost analyses
(BCA) prepared for all future significant regulations under the Clean
Air Act (CAA). Except where explicitly stated otherwise, the provisions
of this subpart do not apply to any other type of agency action,
including individual party adjudications, enforcement activities, or
permit proceedings.
(b) [Reserved]
[[Page 35626]]
Sec. 83.3 What requirements apply to EPA's preparations of Benefit-
Cost Analyses (BCAs) under the Clean Air Act?
(a) Except as otherwise provided in paragraph (b) of this section,
the Agency must develop BCAs of significant CAA regulations in
accordance with best available scientific information and best
practices from the economic, engineering, physical, and biological
sciences, including the following practices.
(1) In preparing the BCA, the Agency must include:
(i) A statement of need;
(ii) An examination of regulatory options; and
(iii) To the extent feasible, an assessment of all benefits and
costs of these regulatory options relative to the baseline scenario.
(2) In preparing the BCA, the Agency must include a statement of
need that provides: A clear description of the problem being addressed,
the reasons for and significance of any failure of by private markets
or public institutions causing this problem, and the compelling need
for federal government intervention in the market to correct the
problem.
(3) In preparing the BCA the Agency must analyze the benefits and
costs of regulatory options, as well as the benefits and costs of other
notable deviations from the proposed for which the Agency is soliciting
comment or the finalized option. Where there is a continuum of options
(such as options that vary in stringency), the Agency must analyze at
least three regulatory options (as provided in section XX(a)(3)(i)) and
explain why these were selected.
If fewer than three options are analyzed, or if there is a
continuum of options and the options analyzed do not include at least
one more stringent and one less stringent option than the proposed or
finalized option, then the Agency must explain why it is not
appropriate to analyze more options.
(4) In preparing the BCA, the Agency must use a baseline that
appropriately considers relevant factors and relies on transparent and
reasonable assumptions. The factors for which the Agency must account
in the baseline include, but are not limited to, the following:
(i) Exogenous changes in the economy that may affect benefits and
costs (e.g., changes in demographics, economic activity, consumer
preferences, or technology);
(ii) Regulations promulgated by the Agency or other government
entities; and
(iii) The degree of compliance by regulated entities with other
regulations.
In rulemaking actions where the Agency determines it is appropriate
to consider more than one baseline (e.g., one that accounts for another
EPA regulation being developed at the same time that affects the same
environmental condition), the Agency must provide a reasoned
explanation for the baselines used and must identify the key
uncertainties in the forecast(s).
(5) In preparing the BCA, the Agency must rely on the use of a
framework that is appropriate for the characteristics of the regulation
being evaluated and must provide an explanation for the approach
adopted.
(6) The Agency must consider how costs and benefits may be affected
by consumer and producer behavior in the baseline and potential
behavioral changes from the policy scenarios.
(7) During the estimation of benefits, the Agency must link
regulatory requirements to the value that individuals place on the
change in benefit endpoints that can be meaningfully attributed to
those requirements. The Agency must select benefit endpoints that the
scientific evidence indicates there is:
(i) A clear causal or likely causal relationship between pollutant
exposure and effect, and subsequently; and
(ii) An anticipated change in that effect in response to changes in
environmental quality or exposures expected as a result of the
regulation under analysis. The Agency must quantify effects for
endpoints which scientific evidence is robust enough to support such
quantification.
(8) The Agency must, to the extent supported by scientific
literature as well as practicable in a given rulemaking:
(i) Quantify all benefits;
(ii) Monetize all the benefits by following well-defined economic
principles using well-established economic methods; and
(iii) Qualitatively characterize benefits that cannot be quantified
or monetized.
(9) When selecting and quantifying health endpoints in a BCA, the
Agency must:
(i) Explain the basis for significant judgments, assumptions, data,
models, and inferences used or relied upon in the assessment or
decision;
(ii) Describe the sources, extent and magnitude of significant
uncertainties associated with the assessment;
(iii) When selecting concentration-response relationships from the
scientific literature, the Agency must select from studies where each
selected study meets the criteria in paragraphs (b)(8)(iii)(A) through
(C) of this section.
(A) The study was externally and independently peer-reviewed
consistent with Federal guidance;
(B) The pollutant analyzed in the study matches the pollutant of
interest in the regulation;
(C) Concentration-response functions must be parameterized from
scientifically robust studies;
(D) When an epidemiological study is used further criteria include
that the study must assess the influence of confounders, that the study
location must be appropriately matched to the analysis, and that the
study population characteristics must be sufficiently similar to those
of the analysis.
(iv) When multiple studies satisfy these criteria the Agency must
characterize multiple concentration-response functions, and, if
appropriate, combine them as a means of providing a broader
representation of the effect estimate. The Agency would also include
studies that meet the criteria above and that do not find a significant
concentration-response relationship.
(v) The Agency must base decisions about the choice of the number
of alternative concentration-response functions quantified for each
endpoint on the extent to which it is technically feasible to quantify
alternative concentration-response relationships given the available
data and resources.
(vi) The Agency must select and clearly identify concentration-
response functions with the strongest scientific evidence, as well as
evidence necessary to demonstrate the sensitivity of the choice of the
concentration-response function on the magnitude and the uncertainty
associated with air pollution-attributable effects.
(vii) Once the Agency has identified the concentration-response
functions to be used for quantifying the selected health endpoints, the
Agency must characterize, in a BCA or related technical support
document:
(A) The variability in the concentration-response functions across
studies and models, including plausible alternatives;
(B) The assumptions, defaults, and uncertainties, their rationale,
and their influence on the resulting estimates;
(C) The extent to which scientific literature suggests that the
nature of the effect may vary across demographic or health
characteristics;
(D) The potential variability of the concentration-response
function over the range in concentrations of interest for the given
policy;
(E) The influence of potential confounders on the reported risk
coefficient;
[[Page 35627]]
(F) The likelihood that the parameters of the concentration-
response differ based on geographic location; and
(G) Attributes that affect the suitability of the study or model
for informing a risk assessment, including the age of the air quality
data, and the generalizability of the study population.
(viii) When feasible, the Agency must use a probability
distribution of risk when determining expected benefits. When it is
infeasible to estimate a distribution, the Agency must use measures of
the central tendency of risk. Upper-bound risk estimates must not be
used unless they are presented in conjunction with lower bound and
central tendency estimates.
(10) The Agency must identify uncertainties underlying the
estimation of both benefits and costs and, to the extent feasible,
quantitatively analyze those that are most influential; and must
present benefits and cost estimates in ways that convey their
uncertainty. The Agency must provide a reasoned explanation for the
scope and specific quantitative or qualitative methods chosen to
analyze uncertainties.
(i) To the extent feasible, the Agency must use quantitative
methods to analyze uncertainties that have the largest potential effect
on benefits or cost estimates.
(ii) The Agency must characterize, preferably quantitatively,
sources of uncertainty in the assessment of costs, changes in air
quality, assessment of likely changes in health and welfare endpoints,
and the valuation of those changes.
(iii) Where data are sufficient to do so, the Agency must consider
sources of uncertainty both independently and jointly.
(iv) To the extent feasible, the Agency must also consider, and
transparently acknowledge, the extent to which qualitatively-assessed
costs or benefits are characterized by uncertainty.
(v) Where probability distributions for relevant input assumptions
are available, characterize significant sources of uncertainty in the
assessment, and can be feasibly and credibly combined, the Agency must
characterize how the probability distributions of the relevant input
assumption uncertainty would impact the resulting distribution of
benefit and cost estimates.
(vi) Except as provided in this paragraph, the Agency must provide
expected-value estimates of benefits and costs as well as distributions
about each of the estimates. In cases where estimates based on expected
values are not feasible, the Agency must present a plausible range of
benefits and costs.
(11) In presenting the results of the BCA the Agency must include
the following elements:
(i) The Agency must present the overall results of the BCA
(benefits, costs, and net benefits of each regulatory option evaluated
in the BCA) in a manner designed to be objective, comprehensive,
reproducible to the extent reasonably possible, and easily understood
by the public.
(ii) The Agency must describe how the benefits and costs were
estimated in the BCA, including the assumptions made for the analysis.
The Agency must describe the models, data, and assumptions used to
estimate benefits and costs, and the evaluation and selection process
for these analytical decisions. The Agency must provide an explanation
of procedures used to select among input parameters to the benefit and
cost models, and any methods used to quantify risk and to model fate
and transport of pollutants.
(iii) Consistent with the best available scientific information,
the Agency must discuss non-monetized and non-quantified benefits and
costs of the action. The Agency must present available evidence on non-
monetized and non-quantified benefits and costs, including explanations
as to why they are not being monetized or quantified and discussions of
what the potential impact of those benefits and costs might be on the
overall results of the BCA.
(iv) The Agency must assess the sources of uncertainty that are
likely to have a substantial effect on the results of the BCA and
present the results of this assessment. The Agency must identify any
data and models used to analyze uncertainty in the BCA, and the quality
of the available data shall be discussed.
(12) To the extent permitted by law, the Agency must ensure that
all information (including data and models) used in the development of
the BCA is publicly available. If the data and models are proprietary,
the Agency must make available, to the extent permitted by law, the
underlying inputs and assumptions used, equations, and methodologies
used by EPA, while continuing to provide appropriate protection for
information claimed as confidential business information (CBI),
personally identifiable information (PII), and other privileged, non-
exempt information.
(b) The Agency must provide a reasoned explanation for any
departures from best practices in the BCA, including a discussion of
the likely effect of the departures on the results of the BCA.
Sec. 83.4 What additional requirements apply to EPA's presentation of
BCA results for all significant rules promulgated under the Clean Air
Act?
(a) The Agency must provide, in addition to the reporting of the
overall results of the BCA as specified in Sec. _._(a)(11)(i), a
summary in the preamble of the overall BCA results, including total
costs, benefits, and net benefits.
(b) The Agency must provide an additional presentation in the
preamble of the public health and welfare benefits that pertain to the
specific objective (or objectives, as the case may be) of the CAA
provision or provisions under which the rule is promulgated.
(1)This presentation must list the benefit categories arising from
the environmental improvement that is targeted by the relevant
statutory provision and report the monetized value to society of these
benefits.
(2) If these benefit categories cannot be monetized, the Agency
must report the quantified estimates of these benefits to the extent
possible and provide a qualitative characterization if they cannot be
quantified.
(c) When the CAA provision or provisions under which the rule is
promulgated contemplate the consideration of specific costs, the Agency
must provide a transparent presentation of how those specific costs
relate to total costs, to the extent possible.
(d) The presentations specified in paragraphs (a), (b), and (c) of
this section must be placed in the same section in the preamble of the
regulation.
[FR Doc. 2020-12535 Filed 6-10-20; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6560-50-P