National Organic Program (NOP); Request for Comment on Organic Livestock and Poultry Practices Economic Analysis Report, 22664-22677 [2020-08548]
Download as PDF
22664
Proposed Rules
Federal Register
Vol. 85, No. 79
Thursday, April 23, 2020
This section of the FEDERAL REGISTER
contains notices to the public of the proposed
issuance of rules and regulations. The
purpose of these notices is to give interested
persons an opportunity to participate in the
rule making prior to the adoption of the final
rules.
DEPARTMENT OF AGRICULTURE
Agricultural Marketing Service
7 CFR Part 205
[Document Number AMS–NOP–20–0037;
NOP–20–03]
RIN 0581–AD75
National Organic Program (NOP);
Request for Comment on Organic
Livestock and Poultry Practices
Economic Analysis Report
Agricultural Marketing Service,
USDA.
ACTION: Request for comment.
AGENCY:
The USDA Agricultural
Marketing Service (AMS) requests
public comment on an Economic
Analysis Report related to the Organic
Livestock and Poultry Practices final
rule (OLPP Rule), published on January
19, 2017, and the final rule withdrawing
the OLPP Rule (Withdrawal Rule),
published on March 13, 2018. The
public comment process for the
Economic Analysis Report is being
conducted consistent with an Order of
the United States District Court for the
District of Columbia, which granted
USDA’s Motion to Remand a legal
challenge to the Withdrawal Rule for
purposes of clarifying and
supplementing the record regarding the
economic analysis underlying both the
OLPP Rule and the Withdrawal Rule.
(See Organic Trade Association v.
USDA; Civil Action No. 17–1875 (RMC)
(March 12, 2020), ECF No. 112).
DATES: Comments must be received by
May 26, 2020.
ADDRESSES: You may submit comments
on this document via the Federal
eRulemaking Portal at https://
www.regulations.gov/. Search for docket
number AMS–NOP–20–0037; NOP–20–
03. Comments may also be sent by mail
to: Dr. Jennifer Tucker, National Organic
Program, USDA–AMS–NOP, 1400
Independence Ave SW, Room 2642-So.,
Ag Stop 0268, Washington, DC 20250–
0268. Instructions: All submissions
lotter on DSKBCFDHB2PROD with PROPOSALS
SUMMARY:
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:46 Apr 22, 2020
Jkt 250001
received must include docket number
AMS–NOP–20–0037; NOP–20–03 or
Regulatory Information Number (RIN):
0581–AD75. You should clearly indicate
the topic to which your comment refers,
state your position(s), and include
relevant information and data to support
your position(s). All comments and
relevant background documents posted
to https://www.regulations.gov will
include any personal information
provided.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
Jennifer Tucker, Ph.D., Deputy
Administrator, National Organic
Program, Telephone: (202) 720–3252.
Fax: (202) 205–7808.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: The
Organic Foods Production Act of 1990
(OFPA), as amended (7 U.S.C. 6501–
6524), authorizes the United States
Department of Agriculture (USDA or
Department) to establish national
standards governing the marketing of
certain agricultural products as
organically produced to assure
consumers that organically produced
products meet a consistent standard and
to facilitate interstate commerce in fresh
and processed food that is organically
produced. USDA’s Agricultural
Marketing Service (AMS) administers
the National Organic Program (NOP)
under 7 CFR part 205.
The Economic Analysis Report
summarizes the agency’s further review
of the Regulatory Impact Analysis (RIA)
for both the OLPP Rule (Final RIA) and
Withdrawal Rule (Withdrawal RIA). The
Economic Analysis Report includes
findings that the Final RIA contained
several material errors. The Withdrawal
RIA corrected some of those errors, did
not identify some of those errors and
thus incorporated them in its analysis,
and did not fully correct one of the
errors. USDA seeks comment on the
findings in the Economic Analysis
Report and their impact on the
Withdrawal Rule. The public comments
will inform a final analysis, to be
published in the Federal Register in the
form of a second document later in
2020, explaining USDA’s final
conclusions pertaining to the Economic
Analysis Report. The full Economic
Analysis Report is included below.
On January 19, 2017 (82 FR 7042),
AMS published the OLPP Rule. After
delaying the effective date of the OLPP
Rule (82 FR 9967, 82 FR 21677, and 82
FR 52643), AMS published the
PO 00000
Frm 00001
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
Withdrawal Rule on March 13, 2018 (83
FR 10775), which withdrew the OLPP
Rule. AMS explained the withdrawal on
the basis that, among other things, the
Final RIA had incorrectly calculated the
costs and benefits of the OLPP Rule and
had wrongly concluded that the benefits
of the rule exceeded the costs. AMS also
published the Withdrawal RIA in
support of the Withdrawal Rule that
sought to correct for three identified
errors in the Final RIA. In the
Withdrawal RIA, AMS found that the
projected costs of the OLPP Rule likely
exceeded its benefits. As separate and
independent bases for the Withdrawal
Rule, AMS also concluded that it lacked
the legal authority under the Organic
Foods Production Act to promulgate the
OLPP Rule and that there was no market
failure in the organic industry sufficient
to warrant the particular regulations
established by the OLPP Rule.
In the fall of 2017, the Organic Trade
Association (OTA) filed a lawsuit in the
U.S. District Court for the District of
Columbia, challenging AMS’s delay of
the OLPP Rule’s effective date; OTA
subsequently amended its complaint to
challenge the Withdrawal Rule. On
October 31, 2019, OTA filed a motion
for summary judgment accompanied by
several extra-record attachments,
including a privately commissioned
analysis of the Withdrawal RIA
performed by Dr. Thomas Vukina, a
consultant and professor of economics
at North Carolina State University. In
the course of reviewing Dr. Vukina’s
analysis, AMS independently
discovered additional flaws in the Final
RIA, which had inadvertently been
carried through to the Withdrawal RIA.
In light of those flaws, on January 3,
2020, USDA filed a motion to suspend
the summary judgment proceedings and
requested voluntary remand. On March
12, 2020, the District Court granted that
request. Subsequently, AMS completed
its initial review of the flaws in the
Final RIA and Withdrawal RIA and is
now publishing the results of the
review, i.e., the Economic Analysis
Report, in this document for public
comment. AMS intends to publish its
final analysis, as informed by public
comment, in time to report back to the
District Court by the court-ordered
deadline of September 8, 2020.
AMS commissioned one of its
economists, Dr. Peyton Ferrier, to
conduct a thorough review of both RIAs
E:\FR\FM\23APP1.SGM
23APP1
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 79 / Thursday, April 23, 2020 / Proposed Rules
and to prepare the Economic Analysis
Report cataloguing his findings. Dr.
Ferrier was not involved in the
administrative processes leading to the
OLPP Rule or the Withdrawal Rule and
therefore was able to provide an
independent perspective on the
integrity of the methodology and
calculations underlying the prior
rulemakings. The Economic Analysis
Report describes his principle findings
and appears below. AMS is seeking
comment on this Report by May 26,
2020.
Economic Analysis Report: Peer Review
of Regulatory Impact Analysis for the
Organic Livestock and Poultry
Practices Rule and the Withdrawal
Rule
lotter on DSKBCFDHB2PROD with PROPOSALS
Table of Contents
Summary
Background
Errors Detailed in This Report
1. Discounting Error in the Final RIA
2. Willingness To Pay Value Was Too High
in the Final RIA
3. Depreciation Errors
A. Depreciation of Future Benefits Error in
the Final RIA
B. Depreciation Treatment Not Fully
Removed From Benefits Calculations in
the Withdrawal RIA
C. Depreciation Treatment Not Fully
Removed From Scenario A Cost
Calculations in the Withdrawal RIA
4. Inconsistent or Incorrect Documentation
of Underlying Assumptions in the Final
RIA
A. Baseline Egg Production Values Used in
Calculations Differ From Those
Described in Text
B. Baseline Egg Production Figures Used in
Final RIA Differ From Those in Cited
Market News Reports
C. Separate Descriptions of Scenario C in
the Final RIA Do Not Match
D. Number of Eggs With New Outdoor
Access Not Stated for Two of Three
Scenarios
E. Benefits Values Reported in Summary
Tables Do Not Match the Text
F. Costs Estimates for Scenario A in Final
RIA Text Are Inconsistent
G. Transposition Error Likely Affected
Scenario C Benefit Calculation in Final
RIA
H. Poor Justification for the General
Specification of Scenario B in Final RIA
5. Error in the Volume Specification
Affecting Benefits Calculations in Two of
Three Scenarios
6. Incorrect Use of the Production Levels
That Do Not Account for Increased
Mortality When Calculating Benefits
7. Errors in Cost Calculations in the Final
RIA
A. Production Levels Used To Calculate
Costs and Benefits Differ
B. AMS Did Not Appropriately Consider
the Costs to Aviaries That Could Not
Obtain Land
C. Production Shares Not Updated for Firm
Exit
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:46 Apr 22, 2020
Jkt 250001
Non-Material Errors in the Final and
Withdrawal RIAs
1. Other Transposition Errors
2. Weighting of WTP values
3. Different Depreciation Periods Are Used
in Different Sections of the Analysis
Summary
On January 19, 2017, the Agricultural
Marketing Service (AMS) promulgated
the Organic Livestock and Poultry
Practices Final Rule (OLPP Rule), (82 FR
7042), and published the associated
regulatory impact analysis (Final RIA).
AMS subsequently completed a
rulemaking that withdrew the OLPP
Rule, (83 FR 10775) (Mar. 13, 2018), and
published the regulatory impact
analysis in support of the withdrawal
(Withdrawal RIA). This Economic
Analysis Report (Report) describes a
number of areas in which the Final RIA
contained flaws in methodology and
calculations that materially affected
AMS’s economic analysis of the costs
and benefits of the OLPP Rule.
The Withdrawal RIA documented and
sought to correct three of these errors:
The incorrect application of the
discounting formula; the use of an
incorrect willingness to pay value for
eggs produced under the new open
access requirements; and the incorrect
application of a depreciation treatment
to the benefit calculations. This Report
identifies four additional categories of
errors in the Final RIA that were not
detected or corrected during the
rulemaking to withdraw the OLPP Rule
and were carried forward into the
Withdrawal RIA. Those errors are:
Inconsistent or incorrect documentation
of key calculation variables; an error in
the volume specification affecting
benefits calculations in two of three
scenarios considered; the incorrect use
of production values that do not account
for increased mortality loss in the
benefits calculations; and aspects of the
cost calculations that resulted in certain
costs being ignored, underreported, or
inconsistently applied.
This Report also identifies additional
issues related to the erroneous
depreciation methodology applied in
the Final RIA. First, the Final RIA
contained errors in its treatment of
depreciation of benefits. The
Withdrawal RIA attempted to correct
the error; however, it did not fully do
so and therefore its final calculations
were inaccurate. The Final RIA
included another error related to
depreciation of costs that was not
previously identified and was carried
forward into the Withdrawal RIA.
In addition to the material errors,
there were minor errors in the Final RIA
and the Withdrawal RIA. This Report
PO 00000
Frm 00002
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
22665
describes three such minor errors that
do not have a material effect on cost and
benefit calculations.
Background
In April 2016 (81 FR 21956), AMS
published the OLPP proposed rule
pertaining to certain aspects of organic
livestock production certified under the
NOP. Among other provisions, the rule
would have imposed stricter
requirements for producers of organic
eggs to provide layers with access to
outdoor space and established stricter
stocking density requirements for
broiler producers. In the preliminary
regulatory impact analysis (Preliminary
RIA), AMS estimated that, despite the
added costs of complying with these
requirements, all existing broiler
producers would become fully
compliant with the new rule. On the
other hand, AMS expected the rule to
cause a large portion of organic egg
producers to exit the industry. At the
same time, because the organic egg
industry had experienced high rates of
production growth in the preceding
years, AMS assumed that the organic
egg industry would grow substantially
throughout the five year period between
the rule’s date of publication and the
date on which it required operations to
become fully compliant. For these
reasons, both the Preliminary and Final
RIAs considered three alternative
scenarios with different assumptions
regarding both firm exit and entry (i.e.,
industry growth). These scenarios and
underlying assumptions about firm exit
and entry were subsequently retained
without change in the Withdrawal RIA.
As stated in the Final RIA (Passage 1,
pages 6–7), these scenarios are:
• Scenario (A)—Full Compliance—
‘‘All producers remain in the organic
market; Organic layer and broiler
populations continue historical growth
rates after the rule.’’
• Scenario (B)—Entry and Exit—‘‘50
percent of organic layer production in
year 6 (2022) moves to the cage free
market. Organic layer and broiler
populations continue historical growth
rates after the rule.’’
• Scenario (C)—Entry and Exit, No
Non-Compliant Entry—‘‘50 percent of
organic layer production in year 6
(2022) moves to the cage free market.
There are no new entrants after
publication of this rule who cannot
comply.’’
Following public comment on the
Preliminary RIA, AMS published the
OLPP Rule and Final RIA in the Federal
Register in January 2017. Between the
Preliminary RIA and the Final RIA,
AMS changed two key assumptions.
First, based on updated data, AMS
E:\FR\FM\23APP1.SGM
23APP1
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 79 / Thursday, April 23, 2020 / Proposed Rules
lotter on DSKBCFDHB2PROD with PROPOSALS
revised its expected growth rate of
organic egg production upward from 2
percent to 12.7 percent, a change that
would directly impact Scenarios A and
B, which assume continued industry
growth.
Second, in the Preliminary RIA, AMS
had previously applied a depreciation
treatment to both costs and benefits
calculations whereby the expected
annual costs and benefits for egg
producers were reduced by onethirteenth (1/13) each year until they
reach zero in the thirteenth year. This
depreciation treatment differs from the
commonly understood accounting
concept of depreciation that converts
the loss in value of a durable asset that
is only infrequently purchased (i.e.,
tractor, barn, truck) to an annual cost.
Instead, the depreciation treatment used
by AMS in the Preliminary RIA was
intended to adjust the costs of
incumbent producers who were precommitted to producing in the organic
industry (due to already owning a layer
house) for the period necessary to
recover the value of their industryspecific assets. After that point, the
costs and benefits realized by these
producers under the OLPP Rule were no
longer deemed to be attributable to the
OLPP Rule and were not included in the
costs or benefits calculations of the
analysis. The justification for the
application of this depreciation
treatment was that, as the value of a
producer’s industry-specific assets
become fully depreciated, that producer
would no longer be treated as precommitted to the industry so that that
producer’s costs and benefits were no
longer, strictly speaking, due to the
OLPP Rule rather than the producer’s
independent decision to stay in the
organic market notwithstanding the
OLPP Rule. In the Preliminary RIA,
AMS based its expected share of
production that becomes fully
depreciated each year on Internal
Revenue Service (IRS) schedules
allowing for 13 years of depreciation for
specialized farm production structures
(see Non-Material Errors (3)). In the
Final RIA, AMS removed the
depreciation treatment from its cost
calculations, but not from its benefit
calculations. In the Withdrawal RIA,
AMS acknowledged that it should also
TB
1
18:46 Apr 22, 2020
1
was assumed to be 12.7 percent in both
RIAs as well, firm entry and exit over
the period between the rule’s year 1
publication and year 6 full compliance
date would potentially have a large
effect on measured costs and benefits. In
general, differences in the assumptions
regarding firm entry and exit can
dramatically affect the calculations of
benefits and costs because these values
are tied to the number of eggs being
produced each year. Certain errors
described by this Report pertain only to
flaws in the analysis of one or two of the
three scenarios.
Errors Detailed in This Report
Below are the descriptions and
analyses of the errors found in the Final
RIA and the Withdrawal RIA.
1. Discounting Error in the Final RIA
As explained in the Withdrawal RIA,
the Final RIA incorrectly applied the
discounting formula to the future
benefits reported in the Summary Table
(pages 6–7) and Table 1 (pages 8–11).
The OLPP Rule considered costs and
benefits over a period of 15 years. With
discounting practices used by
economists, benefits or costs occurring
sooner are more valuable than those
occurring later. To compare costs or
benefits across time, economists apply a
discounting formula that adjusts the
value of future benefits and costs to
their present value equivalent. Guidance
to Federal agencies 2 describes the
rationale for discounting and methods
of its application in detail. Specifically,
to convert future costs and benefits to
their present value, they are to be
multiplied by 1/(1 + r)t where t is the
number of years in the future that the
benefits or costs occur and r is the
discount rate, which the guidance
recommends to be applied at the 3 and
7 percent rates. Benefits or costs that
have been adjusted in this way are
called (discounted) present values.
A total present value of benefits (TB)
can then be calculated by simply
summing the present values of benefits
across years. Denoting the value of
benefits in year t as Bt, the correct
formula for TB over the 15 years
considered in the rule is:
1
1
= B1 X -l+r() + B2 X -l+r() + B3 X -l+r() + ··· + B1s X ( l+r)1
1
1 To avoid confusion, this Report uses year 1 to
refer to the publication date and year 6 to the full
compliance date. The Final RIA and Withdrawal
RIA use 2017 as year 1 and 2022 as year 6 since
VerDate Sep<11>2014
have removed the depreciation
treatment from its benefit calculations
as well.
In March 2018, AMS published the
Withdrawal Rule, after notice-andcomment, and the Withdrawal RIA. The
Withdrawal RIA described three errors
in the Final RIA, which were: (1) The
incorrect application of the discounting
formula, (2) the use of an incorrect
willingness to pay value for organic eggs
produced under the OLPP Rule, and (3)
the application of depreciation to the
values of calculated benefits. These
three errors pertained only to the
calculation of benefits and did not affect
the analysis of costs described in the
Final RIA. With the Withdrawal RIA,
AMS also published a spreadsheet that
contained 10 pages that related Final
RIA calculations to intermediary
components of the benefits calculation
as modified in the Withdrawal RIA.
This document (Withdrawal Workbook)
did not include detailed documentation
to allow simple cross-referencing of
some key figures with the cost and
benefit values presented in the Final
RIA or the Withdrawal RIA. Appendix
A provides that cross-referencing.
Moreover, the Withdrawal Workbook
did not include new calculations for
benefits that corrected all three errors
identified within the Withdrawal RIA,
despite the Withdrawal RIA presenting
values intending to correct all identified
errors. For this reason, the benefit
values in Table C of the Withdrawal RIA
do not correspond to the benefit values
calculated in sheets 6, 7, and 8 in the
Withdrawal Workbook.
The OLPP Rule’s egg producer
requirements did not become fully
effective until the sixth year following
the rule’s publication to give producers
time to come into compliance.1 Both
RIAs assumed that costs of the OLPP
Rule (other than administrative costs,
which are ignored in the analysis)
would first be accrued in the third year
following the Rule’s publication by
producers who would need to acquire
land to meet the OLPP Rule’s space
requirements. The Final RIA assumed
that benefits would not accrue until the
sixth year after publication, when full
compliance was required. These
assumptions were retained in the
Withdrawal RIA. Since annual growth
Jkt 250001
2
3
the OLPP Rule was published in 2017, became
effective one year later, and had a five-year
regulatory phase-in period.
PO 00000
Frm 00003
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4725
5
2 Office of Management and Budget Circular A–
4, dated September 17, 2003, provides guidance on
best practices associated with cost-benefit analysis
to Federal agencies undertaking rulemaking.
E:\FR\FM\23APP1.SGM
23APP1
EP23AP20.016
22666
22667
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 79 / Thursday, April 23, 2020 / Proposed Rules
However, in the Final RIA, an incorrect
formula was used to calculate total
benefits. In the case where r is 3
percent, that formula, denoted
TBIncorrect,r=0.03, was:
1
1
1
In this case, the exponent in the
denominator for all periods after the
second year was incorrectly set to 2.
2
Our estimates suggest that the majority of
consumers are willing to pay an average
premium of $0.21 to $0.49 per dozen for eggs
produced in a cage-free environment with
outdoor access or without induced molting.
Based on this text, the Final RIA
assigned a premium value per egg to the
outdoor access characteristic of $0.49 on
3 The article is titled ‘‘Consumer Attitudes toward
Farm-Animal Welfare: The Case of Laying Hens’’
and published in the Journal of Agricultural and
Resource Economics,38(3):418–434 (2013).
Jkt 250001
r is 7 percent, denoted TBIncorrect,r=7%
below as:
1
1
the high side and of $0.21 on the low
side. However, the Withdrawal RIA
notes that under existing rules, organic
eggs are already required to be produced
cage-free. The Withdrawal RIA notes
that the actual benefit attributable to the
OLPP Rule should be comprised of only
the portion of the WTP described by
Heng, Peterson, and Li (2013) that may
be ascribed to the addition of new
outdoor access requirements to existing
organic egg production requirements.
Table 8 (‘‘Statistics of Simulated WTP
Distributions’’) of the Heng, Petersen,
and Li (2013) study provides estimates
of the WTP for eggs produced by hens
under the new outdoor access
requirements (Passage 3, page 429),
explaining that in a subsample of
consumers that received additional
information regarding the
environmental benefits of cage-free
systems and outdoor access:
3. Depreciation Errors
89% (59%) of respondents were willing to
pay a premium for eggs from hens given
outdoor access (more space), with a mean
premium of $0.25. In [a second] subsample
that did not receive the additional
information, the mean premium for outdoor
access (more space) was lower, at $0.16, with
81% (43%) of those willing to pay a
premium.
To correct for this error, the Withdrawal
RIA therefore replaced the Final RIA’s
high WTP estimate of $0.49 and its low
WTP estimate of $0.21 with new high
and low WTP estimates of $0.25 and
$0.16 (with all dollar values referring to
price per dozen eggs).
This Report finds that the Withdrawal
RIA corrected the WTP value error in an
appropriate manner. We note in (2) of
our Non-Material Errors section,
however, that the correction contained a
minor error that did not have a material
effect on the calculations.
PO 00000
Frm 00004
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
A. Depreciation of Future Benefits Error
in the Final RIA
The Preliminary RIA applied the
depreciation treatment to both the
benefit and costs calculations. The Final
RIA applied the depreciation treatment
only to the benefits calculations, not to
costs. The Final RIA (Passage 4, pages
111–112) states that:
For each cohort, AMS applied the full
compliance costs for each year after the rule
must be fully implemented. These recurrent
costs are incurred through year 15, relative to
the without-regulation baseline. Given the
uncertainty in these cost estimates and
forecasting impacts in the organic egg market,
AMS is presenting estimates without
depreciation to capture the full range of
potential impacts. . . . . While AMS is
presenting the costs associated with this
methodology as the primary costs estimates,
we discuss the rationale for an alternative
methodology based on linearly reducing costs
over the depreciation time period for poultry
houses.
The following description of applying the
depreciation to the cost estimates would
yield a lower cost estimate. This also
assumes that costs only accrue to legacy
organic producers. . . . . [italics added]
The ‘‘alternative methodology’’ text
refers to the method of applying the
depreciation treatment while computing
cost calculations. The ‘‘AMS is
presenting estimates without
depreciation’’ text indicates that costs
calculations in the Final RIA did not
incorporate the depreciation treatment
as they had in the Preliminary RIA.
Finally, the ‘‘assumes that costs only
accrue to legacy organic producers’’ text
explains that the inclusion of the
discussion regarding depreciation
treatment as an alternative rationale was
motivated by the specific assumption
that costs and benefits only arise from
the actions of legacy producers and only
to those producers until their capital
investments under the prior regulatory
regime were fully depreciated.
E:\FR\FM\23APP1.SGM
23APP1
EP23AP20.018
lotter on DSKBCFDHB2PROD with PROPOSALS
2. Willingness To Pay Value Was Too
High in the Final RIA
The Final RIA contained an error that
made the willingness to pay (WTP)
value used in the benefits calculations
too high. Specifically, the Final RIA
drew upon an inappropriate estimate for
the value of eggs produced with the new
outdoor access requirements. This error
was identified and corrected in the
Withdrawal RIA.
The Final RIA drew primarily upon a
2013 article by Yan Heng, Hikaru
Hanawa Peterson, and Xianghong Li
involving a choice experiment
conducted on 924 surveyed consumers.3
In the experiment, consumers were
asked to choose between eggs that differ
in terms of the growing conditions of
the laying hens. Price and growing
conditions were adjusted across choices
to optimize the ability to identify
consumers’ value for eggs produced
under different growing conditions. The
study applied a stated preference
method of estimating the WTP for eggs
that now meet the new outdoor access
requirement in the OLPP Rule. In brief,
the Final RIA focused on the article’s
text (Passage 2, page 419) stating:
18:46 Apr 22, 2020
1
2
= B1 X-C
l+r )1 + B2 X-C
l+r )1 + B3 X-C
l+r )1 +···+Bis X-C
l+r )1
In this case, the exponent in the
denominator was incorrectly set to 1 for
all periods.
This Report agrees with both the
Withdrawal RIA’s assessment and
correction of the discount rate error in
the benefits calculations of the Final
RIA.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
1
2
A different error was present for the
total benefits formula in the case where
1
TB1ncorrectr=7%
'
1
= B1 X ) + B2 X ) + B3 X ) +···+Bis X )
l+r(
l+r(
l+r(
l+r(
EP23AP20.017
TB1ncorrectr=3%
'
22668
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 79 / Thursday, April 23, 2020 / Proposed Rules
Notwithstanding this discussion, the
Final RIA states in footnotes 92 and 94
that the depreciation treatment was
being applied to benefits calculations
because it had also been applied to
costs. Specifically, Footnote 92 (Passage
5, page 97) states:
The 13 year period accounts for the time
needed to fully depreciate layer houses. We
use a 13 year timeframe to align with the
methodology used to calculate the costs,
below [in footnote 94].
In short, despite concluding at pages
111–112 of the Final RIA that it would
not apply the depreciation treatment to
costs, footnote 92 explained AMS’s
application of the depreciation
treatment to its benefits calculations in
the Final RIA as a way to be consistent
with an application of the depreciation
treatment to costs.
The Preliminary RIA included cost
and benefits calculations in which the
13-year depreciation treatment was both
applied and not applied. For instance,
Table 9 (pages 126–127) shows layer
costs as falling in a range each year. The
upper limit to the range is constant and
reflected the estimated costs without the
depreciation treatment. For layers, this
is $28,160,000. The lower limit to the
range is the depreciated value and it
falls by one-thirteenth of the
$28,160,000, or $2,166,000, each year.
The Final RIA’s removal of the
depreciation treatment from costs
appears to have been intended to be
associated with its same removal from
the benefits calculations as well. The
Withdrawal RIA (Passage 6, page 11)
states that:
In initial drafts of the OLPP final rule RIA,
AMS applied a straight-line reduction in both
costs and benefits over time to reflect the
economic life of egg and broiler structures.
Both benefits and costs declined every year
as a fraction of the industry structures
became fully depreciated and reached the
end of their economic lifetimes.
Footnotes 92 and 94 of the Final RIA
show that the depreciation treatment
was not removed from the benefits
calculations in that analysis. The
Withdrawal RIA (Passage 7, page 11)
states as much in the text:
Costs were instead estimated to be constant
over time, but benefits were still straight line
reduced over time. The same reasoning
should have been applied to the benefits to
make the calculation of costs and benefits
consistent.
The Withdrawal RIA calculated new
values for benefits without the straightline depreciation treatment applied.
This Report concurs with the
Withdrawal RIA’s assessment that the
Final RIA contained an error in its
inconsistent application of the
depreciation treatment to benefits but
not costs. However, as we describe in
Section 3.B to follow, the Withdrawal
RIA does not fully address that error.
B. Depreciation Treatment Not Fully
Removed From Benefits Calculations in
the Withdrawal RIA
The Withdrawal RIA attempts to
correct the depreciation error in the
Final RIA by removing the treatment of
depreciation from the calculation of
benefits, but it failed to do so entirely.4
This new benefit calculation has the
following five steps: 5
i. Estimate the number of eggs produced
that would newly have outdoor access, as
defined by the OLPP Rule, after the Rule
takes effect in year 6 (Ey6);
ii. Multiply Ey6 by the WTP for the new
outdoor access to obtain the benefit value by
year;
iii. Apply time discounting to each year’s
benefits (at either the 3 or 7 percent rate);
iv. Sum the benefits over years 6 to 13; and
v. Convert the summed discounted benefits
to an annual benefit over 15 yearly periods.6
The number of eggs projected to be
produced after the Rule took effect
depends on which of the three
scenarios, described in the Introduction
to this Report, is being considered.
Several omissions in the Preliminary
and Final RIAs stymie the independent
review and replication of key figures
provided in the Withdrawal RIA and the
Withdrawal Workbook to this Report.
Those concerns are described in Section
5 of this Report. To assess the
Withdrawal RIA corrections, one can
recover the values for Ey6 in the
Withdrawal Workbook by dividing the
year one benefit values by $0.21 (in the
low case) and $0.49 (in the high case).
Table 1 provides the Ey6 values and the
location where they are stated for each
scenario.
TABLE 1—PRODUCTION ESTIMATES IN THE WITHDRAWAL WORKBOOK
Scenario
Ey6
lotter on DSKBCFDHB2PROD with PROPOSALS
Scenario A ................................................
Scenario B ................................................
Scenario C ................................................
Withdrawal workbook location
355,289,326
97,708,552
89,361,091
Sheet 6—Production with newly acquired outdoor access.
Sheet 7—Production with newly acquired outdoor access.
Sheet 8—Inferred from Values of Undiscounted Benefits.7
The Withdrawal RIA generates benefit
values (i.e., those realized in year 6 of
the analysis period when the
requirement for full compliance takes
effect) based on the WTP values of $0.16
and $0.25 per dozen eggs. The benefits
used in the Withdrawal RIA should be
constant across all years and continue
into year 14 and 15 since they are no
longer subject to the depreciation
treatment. However, in the
implementation of its corrections, the
Withdrawal RIA used the year 6 benefit
value from the Final RIA to determine
the constant annual benefit value with
the depreciation treatment removed.
Since that year 6 value incorporated 5
periods of depreciation treatment
pursuant to the erroneous depreciation
treatment, the value is five-thirteenths
(or 38.4 percent) less than the value the
Withdrawal RIA should have used.
For this reason, while this Report
agrees with the Withdrawal RIA’s
assessment of the Final RIA’s error in
depreciating benefits as described in
Section 3(A), it finds that the
Withdrawal RIA retained a benefits
calculation affected by the flawed
application of the depreciation
treatment methodology and thus failed
to fully correct for that error.
4 Other sections to this Report evaluate the
treatment of depreciation, production growth, and
firm exit from the industry in their totality.
5 Note that these steps are similar to those
described in Footnote 94 of the Final RIA with three
key differences. First, straight-line depreciation
treatment is not applied. Second, discounting is
applied. Third, total discounted payments are
converted to their annual benefit values.
6 This conversion was done using the Microsoft
Payment function. The formula for the annual
benefit, AB, is a function based on r; the discount
rate, N; the number of years (i.e., 15); and TB, the
summed discounted benefits. The value is given as:
AB = (TB × r)/(1¥(1+r)¥N).
7 Sheet 8 erroneously contains the same values as
Sheet 7 for the benefits in its top half. From its
bottom half, the production level of 89,361,091 can
be inferred by dividing the first year undiscounted
benefits value of $18,765,829.11 by 0.21.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:46 Apr 22, 2020
Jkt 250001
PO 00000
Frm 00005
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
C. Depreciation Treatment Not Fully
Removed From Scenario A Cost
Calculations in the Withdrawal RIA
Although the Final RIA stated that it
did not apply the depreciation treatment
to the cost calculations, an artifact of the
E:\FR\FM\23APP1.SGM
23APP1
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 79 / Thursday, April 23, 2020 / Proposed Rules
depreciation treatment actually was
retained in some of its cost calculations.
Table 15 on page 116 of the Final RIA
reported annual costs for Scenario A.
Layer houses were assumed to be
comprised of the same ratio
composition as described (i.e., 70
percent aviaries, 30 percent nonaviaries). Table 15 of the Final RIA
shows that for layer houses greater than
4-years old, costs are $3.81 million in
year 3 (representing one-time landacquisition costs) and $24.29 million
from years 6 to 15; for 2-years old layer
houses, costs are $6.62 million from
years 6 to 15; for 1-year old layer
houses, costs are $13.23 million. Page
111 of the Final RIA assumed that 4year old houses represent 64 percent of
production facilities, 2-year old houses
22669
represent 24 percent of production
facilities, and 1-year old houses
represent 12 percent of production
facilities. Underlying AMS calculations
(described in Section 6 of this Report)
show that the sum of total (physical)
costs and lost revenue is $55.13 million
under Scenario A. Table 2 shows the
decomposition of producers’ costs to the
OLPP Rule by age of operation.
TABLE 2—DECOMPOSITION OF PRODUCERS’ COSTS TO THE OLPP RULE BY AGE OF HOUSE
Share of
houses
(%)
Age of house
Years 6 to 15
costs
(million)
Older than 4-year-old houses ......................................................................................................
2-year-old houses ........................................................................................................................
1-year-old houses ........................................................................................................................
64
24
12
$3.81
$0
$0
$24.29
$6.62
$13.32
Total ......................................................................................................................................
100
$3.81
$44.13
AMS’s removal of the depreciation
treatment from its costs calculations in
the Final RIA implied that the age of
facilities should have no bearing on
annualized calculations of costs.
However, in Table 15 of the Final RIA,
the depreciation treatment was applied
for four years for the 64 percent of
houses that were more than 4 years old.
Rather than using $35.29 million
(= 64% × $55.13 million) for this class
of houses, the number is $24.43 million
(= 64% × (9/13) × $55.13 million).8
Table 15 applied no similar
depreciation to 2- and 1-year old houses
whose values correspond to their
respective share of the market
multiplied by $55.13 million. The
calculation for the 4-year old houses in
Table 15 reflects that the depreciation
treatment was not fully removed from
the cost analysis.
This Report finds that the Withdrawal
RIA’s downward adjustment of costs by
4/13th for houses that are four years old
or greater was inappropriate because,
first, it applies to all costs (i.e., feed,
labor, etc.), not just the industry-specific
assets that depreciate over time and,
second, it is inconsistent with the
ordinary depreciation of assets applied
elsewhere in the analysis (see Final RIA,
page 103). In this case, the downward
adjustment reduced layer costs by 18.2
percent for Scenario A.
lotter on DSKBCFDHB2PROD with PROPOSALS
Year 3 costs
(million)
8 The $24.43 Million figure is stated in cell F29
of the ‘‘Stay in Organic’’ Worksheet of B-Layer,
along with intermediary steps in the equations. The
$24.29 Million figure in Table 2 is stated in the page
1 of the Withdrawal Workbook. This Report cannot
explain the discrepancy in values.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:46 Apr 22, 2020
Jkt 250001
4. Inconsistent or Incorrect
Documentation of Underlying
Assumptions in the Final RIA
This section notes instances where
the Final RIA contained conflicting or
omitted data on key figures used in
calculations and inconsistent
descriptions of certain scenarios
regarding entry and exit. Many of these
omissions or inconsistencies interact
with errors previously discussed in this
Report. This Report finds that, due to
these inconsistencies and omissions, a
knowledgeable external reviewer would
have had substantial difficulty
replicating the key findings of the Final
RIA.9
A. Baseline Egg Production Values Used
in Calculations Differ From Those
Described in Text
In the Final RIA, AMS assumed the
organic egg industry would continue at
its historical growth of an average of
12.7 percent per year during the 6 years
following the publication of the OLPP
Rule until full implementation of the
Rule in 2022. Table 3 of the Final RIA
(page 46) states the baseline quantities
of 325.83M doz. eggs in 2016, 367.21M
doz. in 2017, and 667.63M doz. in 2022.
The Withdrawal Workbook projected
that 390.83M doz. eggs would be
produced in 2017. Footnote 89 (page 96)
and Footnote 94 (page 97) of the Final
9 OMB
Circular A–4 providing guidance on
Federal rule-making states (page 17): A good
analysis should be transparent and your results
must be reproducible. You should clearly set out
the basic assumptions, methods, and data
underlying the analysis and discuss the
uncertainties associated with the estimates. A
qualified third party reading the analysis should be
able to understand the basic elements of your
analysis and the way in which you developed your
estimates.
PO 00000
Frm 00006
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
RIA alternatively list 710.58M doz. in
2022. Both Table 3 of the Final RIA and
Footnotes 89 and 94 of the Final RIA
reflect the assumption of 12.7 percent
annual industry growth, but because the
two sets of numbers have different
starting values, the Final RIA baseline
production figures in Table 3 on page 46
are 6.4 percent lower than the baseline
production figures used in the
calculations in footnotes 89 and 96 in
every year, without any explanation for
that difference. The 390.83M doz. eggs
figure in the Withdrawal Workbook
appears to be based on 14,087,500
organic laying hens reported in the AMS
Weekly USDA Certified Organic Poultry
and Eggs Report first reported for
November 15th 2016.10 In each period,
organic laying hens produced 24.77
dozen eggs per year, a figure that is not
documented explicitly in the Final RIA
(See Section 4.B).11
This Report notes that reproduction of
the Final RIA calculations would be
very difficult without the actual
baseline production estimate and this
number would be very difficult to
ascertain from the Final RIA in light of
the inconsistent figures and omissions
described above.
B. Baseline Egg Production Figures Used
in Final RIA Differ From Those in Cited
Market News Reports
Page 17 of the Final RIA (Passage 8)
states:
In April 2016, AMS Market News
reported 14 million organic layers
currently in production.
10 The 14,087,500 figure is, itself, rounded to
14,000,000 in the analysis.
11 One can only infer the 24.77 dozen eggs per
year value from the Withdrawal Workbook.
E:\FR\FM\23APP1.SGM
23APP1
22670
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 79 / Thursday, April 23, 2020 / Proposed Rules
lotter on DSKBCFDHB2PROD with PROPOSALS
This statement is incorrect. AMS Market
News reported a count of 11,350,500
organic layers in each of the four
reporting weeks in April of 2016 in its
‘‘Weekly USDA Certified Organic
Poultry and Eggs’’ reports. It was not
until November 14, 2016, that the AMS
Market News report began reporting
14,087,500 organic layers.12 The highest
level of organic eggs recorded as being
produced between April 2016 and
January 2017 was 207,497 30-dozen
cases, or 6,224,910 dozen per week.
Based on 52.143 weeks per year, this
corresponds to 324,584,3593 dozen egg
produced per year for an average of
276.49 eggs, or 23.0406 dozen, per
laying hen per year. Separately, the
National Agricultural Statistics Service
(NASS) Chickens and Eggs Summary for
2015, which includes organic and
conventional eggs, lists the average
number of eggs per layer as 276, or 23
dozen, in 2015 and 276.6, or 23.05
dozen, in 2016. In contrast, based on
AMS’s calculation in Tables 6, 7, and 8
of Withdrawal Workbook,13 AMS
assumed, without explanation, that the
average annual dozen eggs laid per bird
was 24.7708. This higher production
value increased the estimated number of
eggs produced by 7.51 percent over the
estimate in the contemporaneous
Market News Report.
This Report finds that the use of the
24.7708 dozen eggs-per-layer
assumption was inappropriate for two
reasons. First, the data source of eggper-layer value used is poorly
documented and significantly exceeds
other readily available data collected by
USDA at the national level. Second, it
deviates from the AMS Weekly Report
data relied upon in the Final RIA for the
layer numbers. It is generally considered
a best practice to use a single, consistent
data set because doing so limits the
possible ways that biases arising from
methodological differences and datacollection error may influence the
analysis.
C. Separate Descriptions of Scenario C
in the Final RIA Do Not Match
The Final RIA calculates costs and
benefits under three sets of assumptions
regarding the entry of operations to the
industry (i.e., industry growth at a 12.7
percent rate in the five years preceding
the full compliance date) and the exit of
operations when firms must become
compliant in year 6. This Report
12 The
AMS Market News report adjusts organic
egg production figures only every month or so.
13 Specifically, 24.7708 Eggs Per Layer is the ratio
of ‘‘Eggs’’ to ‘‘Layers #’s’’ for each year except for
year 4. As explained in the section on Non-material
Errors (1.B), the year 4 Eggs value likely reflects a
transposition error.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:46 Apr 22, 2020
Jkt 250001
previously described Scenario C based
on descriptions from pages 6 and 7 of
the Final RIA. However, pages 98 and
118 of the Final RIA include an
alternative description of Scenario C
(labeled hereafter as Scenario C.2, to
distinguish it from the description of
Scenario C described in the Summary
Table on pages 6–7 in the Final RIA)
that has an important difference
affecting the cost and benefit
calculations applicable to that scenario.
Specifically, Scenario C.2 is described
on page 98 (Passage 9) as assuming that:
. . . 50 percent of current production
would exit the organic market in 2022 and
that there would be no new entrants until
that time. [italics added]
Page 118 seems to reflect the same
description stating:
We base costs on . . . the layer population
in 2017, and no new entrants to the organic
egg market during the implementation period
for this rule. [italics added]
However, page 118 later states that:
In addition, we expect that any producers
who cannot comply with this rule will not
enter the organic egg market during the
implementation period.
The page 98 quote assuming ‘‘no new
entrants until [2022]’’ and the page 118
quote assuming ‘‘no new entrants . . .
during the implementation period
[through 2022]’’ support the description
in Scenario C.2. The second quote on
page 118, suggests, however, that entry
continues but only by compliant
producers. Page 7 of the Final RIA
describes Scenario C similarly to the
description in the second quote on page
118, which suggests that entry (i.e.,
growth) continues but that ‘‘there are no
new entrants after publication of this
rule who cannot comply’’ with the
OLPP Rule. The he ‘‘who cannot
comply’’ language is superfluous unless
there are also entrants who can comply.
If entry (i.e., growth) continues as
assumed by Scenario C, 711 million
eggs are projected to be produced in
year 6 and the share of production that
is already compliant exceeds 50 percent.
If no entry occurs as assumed by
Scenario C.2 (i.e., no growth), 390M
eggs are produced in year 6 and the
share of production that is already
compliant is less than 50 percent. As we
discuss in Section 5, cost and benefit
calculations for Scenario C depend only
on the number of non-compliant
producers that become compliant as a
result of the OLPP Rule in year 6. If a
large number of compliant producers
enter the industry after the rule is
announced, then the share of industry
that is non-compliant in year 6 becomes
smaller. In Section 5, this Report
PO 00000
Frm 00007
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
describes how Scenario C implies that
less than 50 percent of operations are
non-compliant in year 6 so that the 50
percent share of producers that AMS
assumes will remain in the industry
after the OLPP Rule takes effect would
all already be compliant. For this
reason, the discrepancy between the
Scenario C and Scenario C.2
descriptions has a direct impact on cost
and benefit calculations.
This Report notes that confusion over
the exact assumptions involving
Scenario C is likely to have prevented
external reviewers from replicating key
cost and benefit calculations, especially
when this problem occurs in
conjunction with other documentation
errors surrounding baseline production
values.
D. Number of Eggs With New Outdoor
Access Not Stated for Two of Three
Scenarios
Neither pages 97 and 98 of the Final
RIA nor any other section of the Final
RIA states the number of eggs that are
subject to the OLPP Rule (Ey6) in
Scenario B and C. While the Ey6 value
of 97,708,552 for Scenario B was
subsequently provided later in the
Withdrawal Workbook, the Scenario C
value of 89,361,091 is not explicitly
stated and can only be inferred from
calculations in the tables. See Sections
5.G and the footnote to Table 1 of this
Report for discussion. While these
omissions do not represent errors in the
calculations unto themselves, they
would have, especially in conjunction
with other errors mentioned in this
section, severely hampered the ability of
external reviewers to replicate and
examine key calculations regarding both
the benefit and cost calculations of the
Final RIA.
E. Benefits Values Reported in Summary
Tables Do Not Match the Text
The Summary Table (pages 6–7) and
Table 1 (pages 8–11) of the Final RIA
present benefit calculations that do not
match the descriptions of those
calculation on pages 97 and 98 (Passage
10). Specifically, Scenario A benefits:
‘‘. . . range between $13.77 million to $
32.1 million annually with a mean value of
$23 million over a 15-year period.’’
Scenario B benefits:
‘‘. . . range from $3.79 million to $8.84
million per year’’
Scenario C benefits:
‘‘. . . range from $6.93 million to $16.17
million per year.’’
In contrast, the Summary Table and
Table 1 list Scenario A benefits at $16.3
to $49.5 million, Scenario B benefits at
E:\FR\FM\23APP1.SGM
23APP1
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 79 / Thursday, April 23, 2020 / Proposed Rules
$4.5 to $13.8 million, and Scenario C
benefits at $4.1 to $12.4 million.
The Summary Table and Table 1
show the sum of benefits to which
discounting (which had been done
improperly) and the depreciation
treatment have been applied and which
was then converted to an annualized
benefit using the Microsoft Excel
Payment (PMT) function (see footnote
6). The page 97 text, however, presents
the average annual benefits to which the
depreciation treatment but not
discounting had been applied. Also, the
page 97 values do not annualize the
total benefit using the Payment
function, but instead sum the yearly
benefits and then divide that sum by the
total number of years considered, 15.
The Final RIA does not present the
benefit values stated in the Summary
Table and Table 1 elsewhere in the
document, nor does it describe the
function used to convert total benefits to
an annualized figure. These
discrepancies would likely have
prevented a knowledgeable reader from
independently replicating the AMS
calculations.
F. Costs Estimates for Scenario A in
Final RIA Text Are Inconsistent
Page 110 of the Final RIA (Passage 11)
states:
For the organic egg sector, AMS estimates
that the costs of this rule will average $15
million to $21.9 million annually, over 15
years, if all producers comply (the
discounted annualized estimated costs are
$24.7 million to $27.5).
lotter on DSKBCFDHB2PROD with PROPOSALS
These costs align with the cost figures
in the Summary Table and Table 1 for
Scenario A only. Note that across all the
scenarios considered, the discounted
annualized estimated costs of the broiler
rule are unchanged at $3.541 million at
the 3 percent discount rate and $4.092
million at the 7 percent discount rate,
figures reflected in the last two columns
of Sheet 1 in the Withdrawal Workbook.
That same sheet shows that the sum of
the layer and broiler cost components of
the rule is $31.036 million at the 3
percent level and $28.699 million at the
7 percent level. These figures
correspond to the Summary Table
(pages 6–7), Table 1 (pages 8–11), and
Table 15 (page 116) of the Final RIA.14
In contrast, pages 111–112 (Passage
12) of the Final RIA states:
If all currently certified organic egg
producers comply with this rule and the
organic production continues to grow at 12.7
percent each year, we estimated that the
14 Similarly, page 114 also states that ‘‘[i]n
summary, the average annual costs for the organic
poultry sector are estimated to range from $17.4 to
$24.7 million annually over 15 years.’’
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:46 Apr 22, 2020
Jkt 250001
annual cost of the rule is $32.3 million ($17
million at 7 percent discount; 24.2 million at
3 percent discount.)
The preface indicates that this passage
also describes Scenario A but the figures
do not match those previously stated,
any of the figures found in Summary
Table, Table 1, or Table 15 of the Final
RIA, or the figures presented in the first
three sheets of the Withdrawal
Workbook.15 16
G. Transposition Error Likely Affected
Scenario C Benefit Calculation in Final
RIA
The number of eggs used in Scenario
C in the Final RIA should likely have
been 88,822,332 rather than 89,361,091.
The value 88,822,332 is one-eighth of
the total number of eggs produced after
5 years of growth at the 12.7 percent
rate, or 1⁄4 × (24.77083335 × 14,343,051)
where 24.77083335 is the number of
dozen eggs produced per layer annually
and 14,343,051 is half of 28,686,102, the
number of layers after 5 years of growth.
The incorrect value of 89,361,091 (= 1⁄4
× 357,444,364) eggs used in Scenario C
corresponds with the incorrect
substitution of 14,430,050 for
14,343,051. The italicized material
suggests where a transposition error
likely occurred, an error that carried
through from the Final RIA to the
Withdrawal RIA.17
H. Poor Justification for the General
Specification of Scenario B in Final RIA
Scenario B in the Final RIA made the
assumption that between the time the
rule was published in 2017, and five
years later, when full compliance was
required, industry production would
grow at a 12.7 percent annual growth
rate. This rate predicted industry growth
of 81.8 percent from year 1 to year 6.18
Then, scenario B assumes that after 5
years of such growth, 50 percent of
firms would exit the organic egg
industry. Because the ratio of producer
types stays constant, the scenario
15 The Withdrawal RIA made no corrections to
the cost calculations in the Final RIA. For this
reason, an error in the Final RIA cost calculations
extends into the Withdrawal RIA as well.
16 Pages 121–23 of the Final RIA consider
Scenarios B and C together, with Table 16 (page
122) corresponding to Scenario C and Table 17
(page 123) corresponding to Scenario B.
17 The Excel File titled ‘‘C–OLPP All Costs
Benefits FINAL’’ contained the sheet ‘‘Benefits—
cage-free no entry’’ forming some of the calculations
in Sheet 8 of the Withdrawal Workbook. In this
Excel file, the value of 357,444,364 eggs did not
have an underlying formula or source associated
with it, but the 89,361,091 value for the number of
eggs that entered the benefits equation was defined
as 1⁄4 of that value.
18 This rate of growth is substantially larger than
the 2 percent growth rate assumed in the
preliminary RIA and is explained in footnote 131
on page 126 of the Final RIA as reflecting new data.
PO 00000
Frm 00008
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
22671
implies that half of the producers who
entered the industry after the rule was
published in year 1 would then leave
the industry at the compliance date.
Under a modest assumed level of
industry growth, this specification
might be inconsequential. However,
given the high assumed rate of
production growth (81.8 percent), this
specification implies that a production
volume equal to 40.6 percent of the
baseline production level both enters
and departs the organic egg industry
over the span of five years with full
knowledge of the regulatory
requirements expected to cause the
departure of half of the market upon the
compliance date. Page 47 of the Final
RIA seems to preclude this possibility
(Passage 13), stating:
After publication of the rule, AMS projects
continued entry into the organic egg market
(see Table 3). The implementation dates of
the rule as drafted would give those
operations—certified after the publication of
the rule but prior to 3 years after
publication—5 years to comply. This is
intended to provide additional time to
producers who had intended to enter organic
production near the time this rule is
published to prepare land to meet the organic
requirements (the required preparation time
lasts three years). Given that the proposal
was published early in 2016, the majority of
new entrants from publication (2017) until
three years later (2020) would be aware of the
new requirements and construct facilities
that comply with the outdoor space
requirements. Because there is no economic
rationale for a producer to incur the licensing
and construction expenses associated with
organic production, only to be out of
compliance within a few years, late entrants
into the market are assumed to comply.
However, in the cost estimates below, AMS
considered that there may be new entrants up
until full implementation for layers and that
there may be costs to these entrants. We
believe this could significantly overestimate
the costs, but are providing this to capture a
range of potential outcomes given
uncertainties in the underlying assumption.
In Passage 13, AMS states that it
assumes that all late entrants (i.e., those
entering the industry after the rule is
published) would be compliant with the
new rule because there is ‘‘no economic
rationale’’ to believe that they would not
be. However, by allowing for growth in
non-compliant operations, particularly
aviaries, within the underlying costs
calculations, AMS assumed that such
firms continue to enter. The implication
of AMS’s later statement that the
inclusion of ‘‘new [non-compliant]
entrants . . . could significantly
overestimate the costs’’ would only have
the effect of increasing costs in the final
calculations is misleading because a
higher number of non-compliant
operations moving into compliance
E:\FR\FM\23APP1.SGM
23APP1
22672
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 79 / Thursday, April 23, 2020 / Proposed Rules
increases the size of the estimated
benefits. Within the structure of AMS
cost and benefit calculations, operations
that are already compliant with the rule
in year 6 do not create have new costs
to become compliant, nor do they create
any new benefits. As described in
Section 5, if all entrants to the industry
after year 1 are compliant with the new
outdoor access requirement, then greater
than 50 percent of operations are
already compliant in year 6 when AMS
assumes that the 50 percent of
presumably non-compliant operations
leave the industry. This suggests that
there would be no new benefits and no
new costs if only compliant firms enter
the industry before year 6 but after the
OLPP Rule’s publication.
Given the costs and time for firms to
enter the organic industry, this Report
finds that AMS’s assumption that noncompliant operations continue to enter
the industry in the period after the
OLPP Rule’s publication date but before
its compliance date is not well-justified.
5. Error in the Volume Specification
Affecting Benefits Calculations in Two
of Three Scenarios
lotter on DSKBCFDHB2PROD with PROPOSALS
In the Final RIA, AMS stated that the
outdoor access requirement established
by the OLPP Rule for organic egg
production is a ‘‘credence good’’
because it is a characteristic that cannot
be independently verified by the
consumer at the time of consumption
and therefore requires trust in a label to
ascertain that the quality characteristic
is present. AMS did not specify how
consumers of compliant eggs know that
the layers of these eggs have open access
to the outdoors, whether operations
advertise their eggs as having that
characteristic, or whether consumers of
such eggs pay a premium (above the
ordinary organic premium) for eggs with
this characteristic. The presence of such
premiums would likely affect the
content of the RIA. Regardless of these
mechanisms, AMS assumed that only
organic eggs that did not previously
have the outdoor access production
characteristic and now acquired it as a
result of the OLPP Rule would generate
new benefits for consumers.
On page 27 of the Final RIA (Passage
14), AMS wrote:
In response to the descriptions in public
comment, AMS is modifying the estimated
proportion of organic operations that have
adequate land to comply with this rule. In
the proposed rule, we estimated this could be
50 percent of organic egg production. As
discussed above, AMS is assuming that all
aviary operations, which account for an
estimated 70 percent of organic egg
production, would need to acquire additional
land. Based on public comments, we are also
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:46 Apr 22, 2020
Jkt 250001
projecting that a portion, 17 percent, of
single-story (non-aviary) operations, which
account for an estimated 5 percent of all
organic egg production, would also need to
acquire additional land because they may not
have two barn footprints of outdoor space
due to various conditions specific to the
operation.
Scenarios A, B, and C specify that
growth occurs in the industry at a 12.7
percent rate from year 1 to year 6.19
Scenario C (but not Scenario C.2)
indicates that the proportion of facilities
of each type in the industry changes as
the industry grows. The construction of
Scenarios A and B, however, strongly
suggests that there is no change in the
proportions of production facilities of
each type through year 6. Page 27
(Passage 15) then states:
In summary, AMS assumes that operations
representing 75 percent of organic egg
production could incur costs for purchasing
and maintaining additional land to comply
with the outdoor stocking density
requirement.
This statement, in which the outdoor
stocking density requirement refers to
the new requirements for outdoor access
under the OLPP Rule, implies that if the
proportions of all operations of each
type remain in production and no firms
exit the industry (as Scenario A
indicates), then 75 percent of current
organic egg production will gain new
outdoor access as a result of the rule.
Scenario A assumes that all producers
become compliant. The Final RIA
calculates benefits for Scenario A by
multiplying the WTP values by one-half
of year 6 production. In this case,
multiplying production by 50 percent is
likely a correction for the proportion of
existing production that is already
compliant. If so, this proportion likely
reflects the Preliminary RIA’s lower
assumed proportion of production
occurring under aviary systems. The
Preliminary RIA states (Passage 16, page
115):
For this analysis, we assumed that pasture
housing, floor litter housing and slatted/mesh
floor housing systems collectively account
for 50 percent of organic egg production and
either currently comply with the outdoor
space requirements or have the land available
to comply with the proposed outdoor
stocking rate without significant changes to
the number of birds or facilities.
In the Preliminary RIA, AMS assumed
that 50 percent of production was from
non-aviary type facilities (i.e., pasture
housing, floor litter housing, and pit
litter housing systems) and already
compliant with the OLPP Rule and that
19 Non-aviary systems account for 30 percent of
production. One-sixth of these producers (16.67
percent) is 5 percent of all production.
PO 00000
Frm 00009
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
the other 50 percent was of the aviary
type and not compliant. Under these
assumptions for Scenario A (Full
Compliance), the share of production
that would acquire new outdoor access
and provide new benefits to consumers
was 50 percent of production.
In the Final RIA, AMS altered this
assumption and instead assumed that 30
percent of production was from nonaviaries (with only 25 percent of total
production being already compliant)
and that the other 70 percent of
production was from non-compliant
aviary operations. Under these new
assumptions, 75 percent of production
would provide new benefits to
consumers because that is the share of
production not already in compliance
with the OLPP Rule before it takes
effect. For this reason, this Report finds
that calculations in the Final RIA that
assume that new benefits only arise
from 50 percent of the organic egg
produced in year 6 in Scenario A are
inconsistent with assumptions stated
elsewhere.
Scenario B assumes that the industry
and production grow at the 12.7 percent
rate annually between year 1 and year
6 and that 50 percent of current
production exits the industry in year 6
when the rule becomes effective.20 Page
27 of the Final RIA (Passage 15)
indicates that 75 percent of production
must incur costs to become compliant
with the open access requirement. If the
50 percent of production that exit the
organic market are noncompliant
producers, then 25 percent of
production will have been
noncompliant, become compliant as a
result of the rule, and now gained new
outdoor access. Scenario B calculates
benefits based on 25 percent of year 6
production gaining new outdoor access
(which are subsequently multiplied by
the WTP value). This Report assesses
those calculations as being accurate
given the description of assumptions
made on the composition of production
with regard to compliance.
As described previously, Scenario C
assumes that 50 percent of current
production exits the industry in year 6.
Between year 1 and year 6, growth was
assumed to occur at the 12.7 percent
rate but no non-compliant producers
were expected to enter the industry. To
find the amount of production by
incumbent firms that now provide new
benefits to consumers, let QALL be all
producers in year one and 0.75 × QALL
20 In the Withdrawal Workbook, AMS presented
tables that projected future volumes based on a 12.7
growth rate for the entire 15-year period considered
in the analysis. The higher egg volume projections
after year six, however, had no bearing on the actual
calculations of costs and benefits.
E:\FR\FM\23APP1.SGM
23APP1
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 79 / Thursday, April 23, 2020 / Proposed Rules
lotter on DSKBCFDHB2PROD with PROPOSALS
be all non-compliant producers in year
one. If production grows by 12.7 percent
for 5 years, production in year 6 is 1.818
× QALL (=1.127∧5 × Q). Of these
producers, there are still 0.75 × QALL
non-compliant producers in the
industry (i.e., the same number of noncompliant producers from year one).
Subsequentially, the remaining 1.068 ×
QALL are all compliant.
If half of production exits the industry
under Scenario C, then 0.91 × QALL
leave the industry. Presumably, only
non-compliant producers leave the
industry in year 6. This implies that all
of the non-compliant production from
year 1 leaves the industry (0.75 × QALL)
along with an additional 0.16 × QALL of
production that is already compliant.
Since already compliant operations that
remain in the industry do not generate
any new benefits, no new benefits are
created under the assumed conditions of
Scenario C. In the Final RIA, however,
AMS based its benefit calculations on a
production volume getting newly
acquired outdoor access of one-eighth
(12.5 percent) of year 6 production or
0.225 × QALL (=.0125 × 1.818 × QALL) to
calculate its benefit value.21 This Report
finds that the benefit calculation AMS
used in Scenario C is incorrect and
overestimates the total value of benefits.
Alternatively, AMS might have
intended to have described Scenario C.2
rather than Scenario C in its benefits
calculation. Scenario C.2 assumes that
50 percent of current production exits
the industry in year 6 and no growth
occurs until that time (See Section 4.C).
In this case, the benefits calculated for
C.2 would be the same as the benefits
calculated for Scenario B. In that
Scenario, 25 percent of year 1
production (0.25 × QALL) gains new
outdoor access and this volume would
be multiplied by the WTP to find
benefits. Since this also differs from the
0.225 × QALL value used in the Final
and Withdrawal RIAs, this Report also
finds that the calculated benefit for that
Scenario in the Final RIA is inconsistent
with the description of Scenario C.2.
6. Incorrect Use of the Production Levels
That Do Not Account for Increased
Mortality When Calculating Benefits
In the Final RIA, AMS stated that it
expected layer mortality to increase
from 5 to 8 percent as a result of the
OLPP Rule’s new outdoor access
requirement, which exposed layers to
21 The likely transposition error discussed in
Section 5.G affected this calculation. Year 6
production is 710,578,652, or 1.127∧5 (or 1.818)
multiplied by Year 1 production of 390,834,208.
One-eighth of year 6 production is 88,822,332.
Section 5.G describes how that number was likely
incorrectly transcribed to be 89,361,091.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:46 Apr 22, 2020
Jkt 250001
increased risks of disease and predation.
As a result, AMS developed estimates of
after-the-rule production levels that
were 1.4 percent lower than the beforethe-rule levels that specifically reflected
this mortality adjustment. While the
cost estimates correctly utilized the
relevant after-the-rule production level,
the benefits calculations were calculated
based on the quantity levels that did not
take into account the expected increase
in mortality. Details for specific values
of the production before the rule (with
the lower mortality rate) and after the
rule are provided in the following
section. Because the production level
enters into the benefit calculation
multiplicatively, the benefit calculation
is over-estimated by 1.4 percent. This
Report finds that AMS erred by using
the before-the-rule production level
when the after-the-rule production level
was appropriate.
7. Errors in Cost Calculations in the
Final RIA
The cost calculations were not fully
documented in the Final RIA with
regard to how the OLPP Rule affected
average costs across operation types.
This section describes the cost
calculations and notes several concerns,
including how production levels used to
calculate costs and benefits differ, how
AMS did not appropriately consider the
costs to aviaries that could not obtain
land, and how production shares were
not updated for firm exit. By not
appropriately considering the costs to
aviaries that could not obtain land and
not updating production shares for firm
exit, AMS likely underestimated the
costs to implementing the rule in
specific instances.
The main documentation for the cost
and transfer calculations of the Final
RIA was included in workbooks titled
‘‘A–OLPP layer costs—cage free’’ (A–
OLPP) and ‘‘Barn and Layer projections
FR 01 2017 OMB’’ (B–Layer). For the
four types of operations (pasture raised,
floor litter, pit litter, and aviary), the A–
OLPP file enumerates the costs of
producing organic or cage-free eggs (i.e.,
feed costs, machinery, labor, etc.). A–
OLPP documents layer numbers,
production levels, and adjustment
factors including the death loss rate,
which AMS expected to increase under
the OLPP Rule. A–OLPP also reports
calculations for production levels, fixed
costs, variable costs, average total costs,
revenue (based on price assumptions),
and cost differentials before and after
the OLPP Rule. The cost burden of the
rule has two components for egg
producers—increased physical costs
and reduced revenue. In the Final RIA’s
Tables 16 and 17 on pages 122–123
PO 00000
Frm 00010
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
22673
(which correspond to Withdrawal
Workbook sheets 2 and 3), the ‘‘Cost:
Layers’’ column refers to the sum of
increased physical costs and reduced
revenue.
The A–OLPP file has six sheets. The
A–OLPP sheets titled Industry Cost No
Entry (No Entry Sheet) and Industry
Cost Entry (Entry Sheet) calculate total
aggregate costs of the rule, including
increased physical costs and reduced
revenue for all operation types, under
the alternative assumptions that the
industry production did not grow and
that it grew at the 12.7 percent rate. In
the Entry and No Entry Sheets, cell E67
reports total costs, cell E65 reports lost
revenue, and cell E59 reports increased
physical costs. These values are the
sums of the values for each operation
type, with only the pasture raised
operations incurring no additional
increased physical costs or lost revenue.
Cells G36:G38 and D35:D38 show
production levels for each operation
type before and after the rule takes
effect, the difference arising from the
increase in death loss following the
OLPP Rule’s promulgation.22 The
difference between rates of death loss
(reported in cells B18 and B19) drives
the difference in the production levels
before and after the rule takes effect.
The A–OLPP file reports total costs in
year 6 of $55,135,426 in the Entry Sheet
and $30,325,723 in the No Entry Sheet.
These computations do not consider
whether operations exit in year 6, but
are instead based on cells G36:G38, the
production levels after the OLPP Rule
takes effect if all operations are
producing.
Note that production for each
operation in the Entry Sheet is
1.818107555 times greater than its value
in the No Entry Sheet. This indicates
that growth does not change the
proportions of operation types in the
industry. Also, note that production
levels after the rule takes effect (G39) are
1.4 percent lower than their levels
before the rule takes effect (D39). The
higher before-rule production levels
form the baseline production levels in
the benefits calculations.
The A–OLPP total cost values in the
Entry and No Entry Sheets do not
consider the effect of operation exit.
Instead, the B-Layer file adjusts the total
cost values for the shares of year 6
production that remains in the industry
to compute costs under the different
Scenarios. As described in Section 5,
AMS expected different proportions of
the producer types to exit the industry
in Scenario B and C where exit occurs.
22 Death loss rates before and after are presented
in B18 and B19.
E:\FR\FM\23APP1.SGM
23APP1
22674
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 79 / Thursday, April 23, 2020 / Proposed Rules
Specifically, the 70 percent share of egg
production from aviaries would fall to
25 percent and the 30 percent share of
non-aviary production would fall to 25
percent. Since AMS had different cost
calculations for each type of producer,
it should have used these expected
changes in shares to scale costs
specifically by operation type. Instead,
it applied a single scaling multiplier to
total costs (across all operation types)
based on the aggregate share of year 6
production that remains in the organic
egg industry.
In B-Layer, the cell H8 value of
$7,541,431 in the ‘‘Transfer—No Entry’’
sheet describes annual layer costs in
Scenario C, which corresponds to Table
16 of the Final RIA.23 This value reflects
the $30,325,723 total cost from the Entry
Sheet being scaled by 1⁄4.24 The cell H8
value of $13,784,001 in the ‘‘Transfer to
Cage Free’’ Sheet describes annual layer
costs in Scenario B, which corresponds
to Table 17 of the Final RIA.25 This
value is 1⁄4 of the total cost value of
$55,135,426 recorded in the ‘‘Industry
Cost—Entry’’ sheet.26 The interpretation
of the 1⁄4 multiplier is discussed later in
this section.
In B-Layer, the cell H9 value of
$3,812,000 in the ‘‘Stay in Organic’’
sheet reflects the one-time fixed costs of
aviaries acquiring land and is equal to
Scenario A’s year 3 costs in Table 15 of
the Final RIA. Cell H10 of that same
sheet calculates recurring annual costs
of $55,135,426 after year 6. As
previously discussed in Section 3.C,
Table 15 of the Final RIA presents
annual cost figures for layers for three
groups of producers divided by the age
of the producer.27 The values for the
one-and two-year old producer groups
correspond to their share (12 and 24
percent) multiplied by $55,135,426.
Section 3.C describes an error in the
Withdrawal RIA whereby the
depreciation error was not entirely
removed from the cost calculations for
houses older than four years.
The Final RIA’s costs calculations for
layers of a certain type (pasture, floor
litter, pit litter, and aviaries) reflect two
components—increased physical costs
for the portion of production remaining
in the industry and lost revenue for the
portion of production exiting the
industry. For each producer type,
increased physical costs equals the
number of eggs multiplied by the
difference in the estimated average costs
of production before and after the rule.
Lost revenue for layers is the difference
in the number of eggs produced before
and after the rule multiplied by the
break-even organic price before the rule.
Table 3 provides values of average costs
and break-even price 28 for each type of
operation.
TABLE 3—AVERAGE COSTS AND BREAK-EVEN PRICES BY OPERATION TYPE
Operation type
Pasture .........................................................................................................................................
Floor Litter ....................................................................................................................................
Pit Litter ........................................................................................................................................
Aviary (Can Get Land) .................................................................................................................
Aviary (Can’t Get Land) ...............................................................................................................
Average costs
before the rule
Average costs
after the rule
Break-even
egg price
before the rule
$3.0427
1.8972
1.8972
1.8344
1.8344
$3.043
1.947
1.947
1.891
2.399
$3.403
2.121
2.121
2.043
2.043
lotter on DSKBCFDHB2PROD with PROPOSALS
Note: All values are in dollars per dozen.
Scenarios B and C.29 Based on
comments, AMS increased the
production share of aviaries from 50
percent in the Preliminary RIA to 70
percent in the Final RIA, but assumed
that two-thirds of aviaries would not be
able to acquire land. The Final RIA
(Passage 17, pages 27–28) states:
incentivized to remain in the organic market
and obtain needed land.
Since pasture operations are already
fully compliant with the OLPP Rule,
their average costs are equal before and
after the rule. A–OLPP sheet ‘‘LayersAviary’’ provides average cost and
break-even price calculations for both
aviaries that could not obtain land and
aviaries that could. As Table 3 shows,
aviaries that could not obtain land faced
a much higher average cost (after the
rule) than aviaries that could obtain
land. The ‘‘Aviary (Can’t Get Land)’’
average cost values reflect costs if the
baseline aviary’s post-rule production
was one-third of its pre-rule production,
a production level reduction that
mirrors the level of firm exit AMS
assumed for the aviaries after the rule in
AMS is estimating that about two-thirds of
the aviaries, equivalent to 45 percent of
organic egg production, and that a portion of
non-aviary production, which accounts for 5
percent of organic egg production, will not be
able to acquire additional land and will move
to the cage-free market. In summary, AMS
believes that 50 percent of organic
production may transition to cage-free egg
production, while the remainder would be
AMS acknowledges that some producers
may opt to remain in organic production by
obtaining non-adjacent land and
constructing new facilities. While AMS is not
estimating aggregate costs based on
assumptions about what proportion of
organic producers may decide to remain in
organic production by constructing new
facilities, we are providing some parameters
of such costs. Based on information from the
23 The cell I8 value of $170,042,253 is the annual
transfers value reported in sheet 4 of the
Withdrawal Workbook.
24 In the sheet, the $7,542,431 is the sum of four
component values, but each has the same multiplier
and sum to 1⁄4 of total costs in the ‘‘Industry Cost—
No Entry’’ sheet by construction.
25 The cell I8 value of $93,527,000 is the value of
annual transfers value reported in sheet 5 of the
Withdrawal Workbook.
26 In the sheet, the $13,784,001 is the sum of four
component values, but each has the same multiplier
and sum to 1⁄4 of total costs in ‘‘Industry Cost—No
Entry’’ sheet by construction.
27 The distribution of the productive type for this
group is assumed to be the same as it was
previously—70 percent aviaries, 10 percent pasture,
10 percent pit litter, and 10 percent floor litter.
28 The break-even price reflects the (before rule)
average costs with an adjustment for the 20 percent
of output that goes to the less-lucrative breaker egg
market.
29 In AMS cost calculations in A–OLPP, total cost
is the sum of total fixed costs and total variable
costs for a baseline enterprise budget AMS
estimated for a large organic layer operation.
Between firms able to purchase land and firms
unable to purchase land, fixed costs are roughly
equal at $420,626 and $418,234, respectively. On
the other hand, total variable costs differ by
approximately an order of three at $4,236,938 and
$1,552,299. This reflects a production level
differing by approximately an order of three at
2,464,000 dozen eggs for farms that can acquire
land and 821,333 dozen eggs for farms that cannot
acquire land. The average total cost for farms that
can acquire land of $1.8902 per dozen reflects the
sum of fixed and variable costs equaling $4,657,564
divided by 2,464,000 dozen eggs. The average total
cost for farms that cannot acquire land of $2.3992
reflects the sum of fixed and variable costs
$1,970,533 divided by 821,333.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:46 Apr 22, 2020
Jkt 250001
PO 00000
Frm 00011
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
Despite calculating this figure within
internal spreadsheets, AMS did not
apply or publish the ‘‘aviary (can’t get
land)’’ average cost values in the Final
RIA. In the Final RIA, AMS (Passage 18,
page 24) writes:
E:\FR\FM\23APP1.SGM
23APP1
22675
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 79 / Thursday, April 23, 2020 / Proposed Rules
organic egg producers, AMS estimates that
the costs of aviary housing is [sic] $70/hen.
Further, we believe that larger organic
operations have a minimum of 100,000 hens;
medium scale have between 30,000–100,000
birds and smaller scale less than 30,000
birds. Therefore, the corresponding estimates
for housing costs for producers of each size
category: $7 million minimum (large scale);
$2.1–$7 million (medium); $2.1 million
maximum (smaller scale). In addition,
producers that construct new aviary facilities
to house 100,000 birds would need
approximately 6.12 acres of land for housing
and outdoor space. This amounts to nearly
$28,000 in land costs.
Since AMS deviated from those provisions,
we are not utilizing the associated cost
projections. [italics added]
In the first italicized passage, AMS
states that some aviary operations that
could not acquire additional (adjacent)
land might be forced to buy land
elsewhere and build new facilities to
remain in operation. AMS then outlines
‘‘parameters of such [building] costs’’
before stating in the second italicized
passage that it would not utilize these
costs.
Table 4 lists the production levels
before and after the OLPP Rule for each
type of operation for Scenario A. The
total level of eggs before accounting for
the rule’s impact on mortality—
710,578,627 dozen—corresponds to the
level of eggs in year 6 as listed on Table
6 of the Withdrawal Workbook. The
numbers of eggs before and after the rule
differ because AMS expected layer
mortality to increase with outdoor
access. As we note in Section 6, AMS
used the higher before-the-rule
production level rather than the lower
after-the-rule production levels in the
benefits calculations and this led to
their over-estimation.
TABLE 4—PRODUCTION VALUES, COST INCREASES, AND LOST REVENUES FROM ENTRY SHEET
Type
Eggs after rule
Eggs before rule
Increased costs
Lost revenue
Pasture .............................................................................................
Fl. Litter ............................................................................................
Pit Litter ............................................................................................
Aviary ...............................................................................................
64,495,917
70,682,553
70,682,553
494,777,870
64,495,917
71,786,968
71,786,968
502,508,774
$0
3,506,265
3,507,153
27,641,969
$0
2,343,009
2,343,009
15,794,020
Total ..........................................................................................
700,638,893
710,578,627
34,655,387
20,480,038
Increased costs and lost revenues equal
$55,134,539. As we note in Section 3.C,
this value would have been the total
cost to egg producers in Scenario A if
the depreciation treatment had not been
applied for 4-year-old houses. This
value is the sum of total increased
costs—$34,655,387—and total lost
revenue—$20,480,038. Importantly, the
computation for increased costs for
aviaries uses only the average costs for
aviaries that can obtain land. Because
AMS estimated that about 45 percent of
production was comprised of aviaries
that could not obtain land and because
these aviaries have far higher costs than
aviaries that can obtain land, using only
the average cost for aviaries that can
obtain land for all aviaries will lead
AMS estimate of costs for Scenario A to
be underestimated.
Under Scenario B, the organic egg
industry grows at a 12.7 percent rate
between year 1 and year 6, after which
time half of the market participants
leave the industry. To obtain the
increased costs estimate, AMS used 1⁄4
of the year 6 production levels for each
type of operation and then multiplied
these values by the difference in average
costs before and after the OLPP Rule, as
with Scenario A. Similarly, for
decreased revenues, AMS used
production values before and after the
rule that were 1⁄4 of the values used in
Scenario A. This Report notes that
production levels enter linearly into the
formulas for increased costs and lost
revenue. As a result, the total costs
reported in Table 17 for layers are
$13,784,000.
In Scenario C, the industry grows at
the 12.7 percent rate with no entry from
non-compliant producers and then, in
year 6, 50 percent of producers exit and
transition to cage-free production. Table
5 below shows the level of eggs
produced before and after the OLPP
Rule with no growth. Based on these
levels, Table 5 shows that total
increased costs are $19,061,241 and lost
revenue is $11,264,482 so that total
costs are $30,325,723. As with Scenario
B, the numbers of eggs used in the
calculations (both before and after the
rule) are multiplied by 1⁄4 and the
estimated value calculated for Scenario
B is 1⁄4 of $30,325,723 (the sum of
increased costs and lost revenue) in
Table 5 below, or $7,541,431.
TABLE 5—PRODUCTION, INCREASED COSTS, AND LOST REVENUES FROM A–OLPP NO ENTRY SHEET
lotter on DSKBCFDHB2PROD with PROPOSALS
Type
Eggs after rule
Eggs before rule
Increased costs
Lost revenue
Pasture .............................................................................................
Fl. Litter ............................................................................................
Pit Litter ............................................................................................
Aviary ...............................................................................................
35,474,203
38,876,992
38,876,992
272,138,944
35,474,203
39,484,445
39,484,445
276,391,115
$0
1,928,524
1,929,013
15,203,704
$0
1,288,707
1,288,707
8,687,067
Total ..........................................................................................
385,367,131
390,834,208
19,061,241
11,264,482
Based on these figures, this Report finds
three errors with the cost calculations in
the Final RIA, as described in the
following sections.
A. Production Levels Used To Calculate
Costs and Benefits Differ
additional land to comply with the outdoor
stocking density requirement.
The Final RIA (Passage 19, page 27)
indicates that:
Seventy five percent of the year 6
production (711 million dozen eggs) is
532 million dozen eggs. In its
calculation of benefits, AMS sought to
include only benefits from production
AMS assumes that operations representing
75 percent of organic egg production could
incur costs for purchasing and maintaining
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:46 Apr 22, 2020
Jkt 250001
PO 00000
Frm 00012
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
E:\FR\FM\23APP1.SGM
23APP1
22676
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 79 / Thursday, April 23, 2020 / Proposed Rules
of organic eggs that gained new outdoor
access as defined under the OLPP Rule
and used 50 percent of year 6
production, or 355,289,326 dozen eggs,
to reflect that production. The share of
houses that were projected to gain new
outdoor access under this scenario is
higher than 50 percent because, at a
minimum, all aviary production
remaining in the industry would gain
outdoor access and aviaries comprise 70
percent of production. For this reason,
this Report finds that the assumed 50
percent share of production that gains
new outdoor access is inconsistent with
the page 27 text.30
In Scenario B, AMS computes costs
based on 1⁄4 of total costs in the Entry
Sheet (relating to year 1 production
levels). In the benefits section, AMS
computes benefits based on 1⁄8 (of year
6) production (after correcting for the
error described in Section 3.C). In this
case, AMS assumed that only 50 percent
of production would gain new outdoor
access as a result of the OLPP Rule and
thereby create new consumer benefits.
However, this Report finds the 50
percent share to be inconsistent with the
page 27 text indicated that 75 percent of
production would need to acquire land
to gain new outdoor access and its costs
calculations that approximately 90
percent of production volume pays a
higher cost.
For Scenario C, AMS computes costs
based on 1⁄4 of total costs reported in the
No Entry Sheet (relating to year 1
production levels) but computes
benefits based on 1⁄8 of year 1
production. Following the same logic as
with Scenarios A and B, this Report
finds the 50 percent share to be
inconsistent with the page 27 text.
lotter on DSKBCFDHB2PROD with PROPOSALS
B. AMS Did Not Appropriately Consider
the Costs to Aviaries That Could Not
Obtain Land
Aviaries comprised 70 percent of
organic egg production and AMS
estimated that approximately two-thirds
of aviary producers would be unable to
acquire the land required under the
OLPP Rule. Scenario A calculates costs
under the assumption that all current
30 Despite the page 27 statement that 75 percent
of production would need to purchase additional
land, the Entry and No Entry Sheets describe three
producer types (pit-litter, floor-litter, and aviary)
that comprise 90 percent of production and would
incur increased costs as a result of the OLPP Rule.
A close reading of the cost figures in A–OLPP
indicates that little or no cost for added land for pitlitter and floor-litter producers was included in the
cost calculations. It is unclear whether AMS
considered production that gained outdoor access
under the rule as production by operations paying
additional costs under the rule or firms needing to
acquire land under the rule. If it is firms needing
to acquire land, the 75 percent figure may be
accurate.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:46 Apr 22, 2020
Jkt 250001
firms continue to operate under the new
rule conditions, regardless of their
ability to acquire additional land.
Whether aviaries would become
compliant by acquiring non-adjacent
land and building new facilities (as
suggested in Passage 17) or reducing
production volumes is unclear. Despite
acknowledging that the aviaries that
comprised 45 percent of production that
could not acquire land would face far
higher average costs than the aviaries
comprising 25 percent of production
that could acquire land, AMS applied
the lower average cost to all aviaries.
This Report further notes that because
AMS did not present any of these key
underlying cost calculations in the Final
RIA, outside reviewers may not have
been aware of the modeling
specification. Despite stating in Passage
18 that a cost estimate for aviaries that
could not acquire land would not be
used, this Report finds that AMS still
did not fully explain why the lower cost
estimate was used and concludes that
costs for Scenario A were
underestimated as a result.
C. Production Shares Not Updated for
Firm Exit
In Scenarios B and C, AMS assumed
that, following industry growth for five
years, 50 percent of firms exit the
industry as a result of the rule. In
Passage 17, AMS indicated that 2⁄3 of
aviaries would exit the industry after
the OLPP Rule took effect. This implies
that the ratio of aviaries to non-aviaries
(pasture, floor litter, and pit litter) falls
considerably after the rule. In Scenario
B, however, AMS used cost calculations
that assume the shares of operation
types are unchanged. This is significant
for two reasons. First, a larger share of
remaining firms may be comprised of
pastured raised operations. Within the
context of the AMS analysis, an
increased share of pasture raised
operations causes both costs and
benefits to fall. This occurs because
operations that are already compliant
with the rule do not produce any new
benefit after the rule takes effect and do
not incur any costs to become
compliant.
Second, a change in the composition
of operations after the rule takes effect
is likely to cause the average price of
eggs to increase to reflect its new higher
break-even level across all producers.
Following the rule, firms will exit the
industry if the average price of eggs is
less than the break-even price. Price,
however, will rise as firms leave the
industry. Eventually, the average price
reaches the break-even price level and
firms no longer exit the market. If the
proportion of firm types is unchanged,
PO 00000
Frm 00013
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
the increase in the break-even will be
close to the average cost of
implementing the rule. Table 3 indicates
that the maximum change in average
costs across all operations is relatively
small at 6 cents. Pasture raised
operations, however, have far higher
average costs (and related break-even
costs) before the rule than other
operation types. By assuming that the
share of producer types is unchanged
after the rule, AMS constrained the
rule’s effect on the break-even price to
be the cost of compliance (i.e., the
change in average costs) within an
operation type and precluded a separate
industry composition effect due to the
industry shift from aviaries to nonaviaries. This industry composition
effect will increase production costs on
average for the industry independent of
the increased cost of compliance.
Non-Material Errors in the Final and
Withdrawal RIAs
1. Other Transposition Errors
a. Costs in Withdrawal RIA—In the
Withdrawal RIA’s Table C, the cost
savings are erroneously stated as ‘‘$28.7
to $29.9’’ under the assumed conditions
of: ‘‘All producers remain in organic
market; Organic layer and broiler
populations continue growth rates after
rule.’’ The correct values are reported in
Table A as: ‘‘$28.7 to $31.0.’’
b. Year 4 Egg Production—The
Withdrawal Workbook Sheets 6, 7, 8,
and 9 list 599,453,903 eggs being
produced in year 4. Based on the stated
12.7% growth rate this value should
have been 559,453,904. The italicized
material suggests that a transposition
error likely occurred.
2. Weighting of WTP Values
This Report notes that Passage 1 refers
to the WTP of ‘‘the majority of the
consumers’’ while Passage 2 refers to
the ‘‘mean premium’’ for each of the two
subsets of additional consumers’ WTP.
This Report assesses the mean premium
as the more appropriate value to apply
for rulemaking purposes. This rationale
is not cited in the Withdrawal RIA but
supports AMS’s decision to correct the
Final RIA numbers.
This Report also notes that Table 8
provides WTP estimates (identical to the
‘‘mean premium’’ cited in Passage 2) for
two other subsets of all consumers—
consumers differing by their perception
of quality of an animal-friendly product
and consumers differing by their
perception of management practices on
hen welfare. In the Final RIA and
Withdrawal RIA, the high-end and lowend values for the WTP are then used
to create separate high-end and low-end
E:\FR\FM\23APP1.SGM
23APP1
lotter on DSKBCFDHB2PROD with PROPOSALS
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 79 / Thursday, April 23, 2020 / Proposed Rules
estimates of the benefits under the rule.
Also, despite the availability of the
other subsets, only the ‘‘receiving of
additional information’’ subset is used
for the high and low values. Later those
two estimates are averaged in the
computation of the net benefits of the
rule without regard for any weighing of
what proportions of consumers actually
belong to those subsets.
From a methodological standpoint,
this Report notes that the use of the
estimate of the ‘‘receiving of additional
information’’ subset, rather than the
other subsets, is inappropriate. The
‘‘receiving of additional information’’ is
a treatment variable where subjects
receive additional information (relative
to the control treatment of no additional
information) on the environmental
consequences of their choices. The other
two subsets—consumers organized by
perception of quality and consumers
organized by perception of
management—represent true control
variables because they reflect consumer
perceptions formed outside of the
choice experiment, as opposed to
information provided by the
experimental designers. A more
appropriate method of developing and
compiling the WTP from the two
subsets would have been to use values
of the WTP from one of the two control
groups and weight their effect on the
final benefit values by the share of
consumers in each group. In the case of
the information provided, there is no
reason to assume that the proportion of
the consumers to which the authors
provided this information is equal to the
share of actual consumers purchasing
eggs who might have that information.
Despite the methodological concerns
in the choice of subsets and the
weighting of the subset groups, benefit
calculations are unlikely to change
materially when either change is
applied. Because the ‘‘received
additional information’’ and ‘‘did not
receive additional information’’
treatment groups had nearly equal
numbers of consumers—499 and 475—
the weighted and unweighted
averages—20.5 cents and 20.2 cents—
are very similar. Moreover, the weighted
averages of the other two subsets—20.9
cents for ‘‘perceptions of quality’’ and
20.3 cents for ‘‘perception of
management practices’’—are very
similar to the ‘‘received additional
information’’ subset.
This Report concurs with the
assessment of the Withdrawal RIA that
the Final RIA used inappropriate values
for the WTP in its calculation of the
benefits. The Report cites two
methodological concerns in the
Withdrawal RIA’s correction of this
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:46 Apr 22, 2020
Jkt 250001
error. However, this Report also notes
that using benefits values with a more
appropriate specification in the benefits
calculation would not change the
findings substantially.
3. Different Depreciation Periods Are
Used in Different Sections of the
Analysis
In the proposed OLPP Rule published
April 13, 2016 (81 FR 21956), AMS
states that it applied a depreciation
period for hen layer houses of either
12.5 or 13 years, the difference
presumably reflecting the need for a
round number. AMS applied the
depreciation rate in three ways. First, a
12.5-year depreciation period is used to
set the compliance phase period.
Specifically, in the proposed OLPP
Rule, AMS states that the difference
between the depreciation rate (12.5
years) and average age of organic aviary
layer houses (7.6 years) is roughly 5
years. Therefore, a 5-year
implementation period would allow
organic egg producers, on average, to
recover the costs of a poultry house. 71
FR 21986.
Second, a 13-year period is used in
the depreciation treatment of costs and
benefits in the proposed OLPP Rule.
Despite the errors already mentioned in
this section, the depreciation treatment
was intended to be removed from
calculations in the Final RIA. Third,
AMS followed the standard accounting
practice of converting the single period
cost of a durable asset to a recurring
annual cost using the depreciation
concept. In this method, AMS divided
an asset’s costs by its depreciable life to
create an equivalent annual cost in
using the asset. In using a longer
depreciation period of 20 rather than 13
years, AMS decreased the annual costs
of using the asset by approximately 35
percent (7/20).31 However, since this
asset depreciation cost (the term being
used in the ordinary accounting sense)
is a relatively small portion of annual
costs, this Report assesses this
discrepancy as being non-material.
Appendix A—Cross Referencing of
Withdrawal Workbook Page Numbers
and Final RIA Tables
• Withdrawal Workbook Sheet 1
corresponds to Final RIA, Table 15 titled
‘‘Estimated costs for organic egg and poultry
sector—full compliance.’’
• Withdrawal Workbook Sheet 2
corresponds to Final RIA, Table 16 titled
‘‘Estimated cost for organic egg and poultry
31 If a 20-year depreciation period is used, then
annual costs are 5 percent of the asset’s cost. If a
13-year depreciation period is used, then annual
costs are 7.69 percent of the asset’s cost.
PO 00000
Frm 00014
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
22677
production—some operations move to cage
free in year 6 (2022).’’
• Withdrawal Workbook Sheet 3
corresponds to Final RIA, Table 17 titled
‘‘Estimated cost for organic egg and poultry
production—some operations move to cage
free in year 6 (2022); new entry continues
after rule.’’
• Withdrawal Workbook Sheet 4
corresponds to Final RIA, Table 18 titled
‘‘Estimated transfers (foregone profit) for
organic egg and poultry production—some
operations move to cage free in year 6
(2022).’’
• Withdrawal Workbook Sheet 5
corresponds to Final RIA, Table 19 titled
‘‘Estimated cost for organic egg and poultry
production—some operations move to cage
free in year 6 (2022); new entry continues
after rule.’’
• Withdrawal Workbook Sheet 6 includes
intermediate calculations to support the
benefit figures associated with Scenario A.
• Withdrawal Workbook Sheet 7 includes
intermediate calculations to support the
benefit figures associated with Scenario B.
• Withdrawal Workbook Sheet 8 includes
intermediate calculations to support the
benefit figures associated with Scenario C.
• Withdrawal Workbook Sheet 9
corresponds to Figure 6 of the Final RIA.
• Withdrawal Workbook Sheet 10 includes
calculations based on data from the National
Animal Health Monitoring Survey that
describes the age distribution of layer houses.
Bruce Summers,
Administrator, Agricultural Marketing
Service.
[FR Doc. 2020–08548 Filed 4–22–20; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE P
DEPARTMENT OF ENERGY
10 CFR Part 431
[EERE–2020–BT–PET–0003]
Energy Efficiency Program for
Industrial Equipment: Test Procedures
for Fans, Notice of Petition for
Rulemaking
Office of Energy Efficiency and
Renewable Energy, Department of
Energy.
ACTION: Notice of petition for
rulemaking; request for comments.
AGENCY:
This document announces
receipt of a petition received by DOE on
January 10, 2020, from the Air
Movement and Control Association
(AMCA), International, Air
Conditioning Contractors of America,
and Sheet Metal & Air Conditioning
Contractors of America requesting that
DOE establish a Federal test procedure
for commercial and industrial fans. The
petition, which appears at the end of
this document, requests that DOE
resume a previous DOE rulemaking
effort to establish a Federal test
SUMMARY:
E:\FR\FM\23APP1.SGM
23APP1
Agencies
[Federal Register Volume 85, Number 79 (Thursday, April 23, 2020)]
[Proposed Rules]
[Pages 22664-22677]
From the Federal Register Online via the Government Publishing Office [www.gpo.gov]
[FR Doc No: 2020-08548]
========================================================================
Proposed Rules
Federal Register
________________________________________________________________________
This section of the FEDERAL REGISTER contains notices to the public of
the proposed issuance of rules and regulations. The purpose of these
notices is to give interested persons an opportunity to participate in
the rule making prior to the adoption of the final rules.
========================================================================
Federal Register / Vol. 85, No. 79 / Thursday, April 23, 2020 /
Proposed Rules
[[Page 22664]]
DEPARTMENT OF AGRICULTURE
Agricultural Marketing Service
7 CFR Part 205
[Document Number AMS-NOP-20-0037; NOP-20-03]
RIN 0581-AD75
National Organic Program (NOP); Request for Comment on Organic
Livestock and Poultry Practices Economic Analysis Report
AGENCY: Agricultural Marketing Service, USDA.
ACTION: Request for comment.
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
SUMMARY: The USDA Agricultural Marketing Service (AMS) requests public
comment on an Economic Analysis Report related to the Organic Livestock
and Poultry Practices final rule (OLPP Rule), published on January 19,
2017, and the final rule withdrawing the OLPP Rule (Withdrawal Rule),
published on March 13, 2018. The public comment process for the
Economic Analysis Report is being conducted consistent with an Order of
the United States District Court for the District of Columbia, which
granted USDA's Motion to Remand a legal challenge to the Withdrawal
Rule for purposes of clarifying and supplementing the record regarding
the economic analysis underlying both the OLPP Rule and the Withdrawal
Rule. (See Organic Trade Association v. USDA; Civil Action No. 17-1875
(RMC) (March 12, 2020), ECF No. 112).
DATES: Comments must be received by May 26, 2020.
ADDRESSES: You may submit comments on this document via the Federal
eRulemaking Portal at https://www.regulations.gov/. Search for docket
number AMS-NOP-20-0037; NOP-20-03. Comments may also be sent by mail
to: Dr. Jennifer Tucker, National Organic Program, USDA-AMS-NOP, 1400
Independence Ave SW, Room 2642-So., Ag Stop 0268, Washington, DC 20250-
0268. Instructions: All submissions received must include docket number
AMS-NOP-20-0037; NOP-20-03 or Regulatory Information Number (RIN):
0581-AD75. You should clearly indicate the topic to which your comment
refers, state your position(s), and include relevant information and
data to support your position(s). All comments and relevant background
documents posted to https://www.regulations.gov will include any
personal information provided.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: Jennifer Tucker, Ph.D., Deputy
Administrator, National Organic Program, Telephone: (202) 720-3252.
Fax: (202) 205-7808.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: The Organic Foods Production Act of 1990
(OFPA), as amended (7 U.S.C. 6501-6524), authorizes the United States
Department of Agriculture (USDA or Department) to establish national
standards governing the marketing of certain agricultural products as
organically produced to assure consumers that organically produced
products meet a consistent standard and to facilitate interstate
commerce in fresh and processed food that is organically produced.
USDA's Agricultural Marketing Service (AMS) administers the National
Organic Program (NOP) under 7 CFR part 205.
The Economic Analysis Report summarizes the agency's further review
of the Regulatory Impact Analysis (RIA) for both the OLPP Rule (Final
RIA) and Withdrawal Rule (Withdrawal RIA). The Economic Analysis Report
includes findings that the Final RIA contained several material errors.
The Withdrawal RIA corrected some of those errors, did not identify
some of those errors and thus incorporated them in its analysis, and
did not fully correct one of the errors. USDA seeks comment on the
findings in the Economic Analysis Report and their impact on the
Withdrawal Rule. The public comments will inform a final analysis, to
be published in the Federal Register in the form of a second document
later in 2020, explaining USDA's final conclusions pertaining to the
Economic Analysis Report. The full Economic Analysis Report is included
below.
On January 19, 2017 (82 FR 7042), AMS published the OLPP Rule.
After delaying the effective date of the OLPP Rule (82 FR 9967, 82 FR
21677, and 82 FR 52643), AMS published the Withdrawal Rule on March 13,
2018 (83 FR 10775), which withdrew the OLPP Rule. AMS explained the
withdrawal on the basis that, among other things, the Final RIA had
incorrectly calculated the costs and benefits of the OLPP Rule and had
wrongly concluded that the benefits of the rule exceeded the costs. AMS
also published the Withdrawal RIA in support of the Withdrawal Rule
that sought to correct for three identified errors in the Final RIA. In
the Withdrawal RIA, AMS found that the projected costs of the OLPP Rule
likely exceeded its benefits. As separate and independent bases for the
Withdrawal Rule, AMS also concluded that it lacked the legal authority
under the Organic Foods Production Act to promulgate the OLPP Rule and
that there was no market failure in the organic industry sufficient to
warrant the particular regulations established by the OLPP Rule.
In the fall of 2017, the Organic Trade Association (OTA) filed a
lawsuit in the U.S. District Court for the District of Columbia,
challenging AMS's delay of the OLPP Rule's effective date; OTA
subsequently amended its complaint to challenge the Withdrawal Rule. On
October 31, 2019, OTA filed a motion for summary judgment accompanied
by several extra-record attachments, including a privately commissioned
analysis of the Withdrawal RIA performed by Dr. Thomas Vukina, a
consultant and professor of economics at North Carolina State
University. In the course of reviewing Dr. Vukina's analysis, AMS
independently discovered additional flaws in the Final RIA, which had
inadvertently been carried through to the Withdrawal RIA.
In light of those flaws, on January 3, 2020, USDA filed a motion to
suspend the summary judgment proceedings and requested voluntary
remand. On March 12, 2020, the District Court granted that request.
Subsequently, AMS completed its initial review of the flaws in the
Final RIA and Withdrawal RIA and is now publishing the results of the
review, i.e., the Economic Analysis Report, in this document for public
comment. AMS intends to publish its final analysis, as informed by
public comment, in time to report back to the District Court by the
court-ordered deadline of September 8, 2020.
AMS commissioned one of its economists, Dr. Peyton Ferrier, to
conduct a thorough review of both RIAs
[[Page 22665]]
and to prepare the Economic Analysis Report cataloguing his findings.
Dr. Ferrier was not involved in the administrative processes leading to
the OLPP Rule or the Withdrawal Rule and therefore was able to provide
an independent perspective on the integrity of the methodology and
calculations underlying the prior rulemakings. The Economic Analysis
Report describes his principle findings and appears below. AMS is
seeking comment on this Report by May 26, 2020.
Economic Analysis Report: Peer Review of Regulatory Impact Analysis for
the Organic Livestock and Poultry Practices Rule and the Withdrawal
Rule
Table of Contents
Summary
Background
Errors Detailed in This Report
1. Discounting Error in the Final RIA
2. Willingness To Pay Value Was Too High in the Final RIA
3. Depreciation Errors
A. Depreciation of Future Benefits Error in the Final RIA
B. Depreciation Treatment Not Fully Removed From Benefits
Calculations in the Withdrawal RIA
C. Depreciation Treatment Not Fully Removed From Scenario A Cost
Calculations in the Withdrawal RIA
4. Inconsistent or Incorrect Documentation of Underlying
Assumptions in the Final RIA
A. Baseline Egg Production Values Used in Calculations Differ
From Those Described in Text
B. Baseline Egg Production Figures Used in Final RIA Differ From
Those in Cited Market News Reports
C. Separate Descriptions of Scenario C in the Final RIA Do Not
Match
D. Number of Eggs With New Outdoor Access Not Stated for Two of
Three Scenarios
E. Benefits Values Reported in Summary Tables Do Not Match the
Text
F. Costs Estimates for Scenario A in Final RIA Text Are
Inconsistent
G. Transposition Error Likely Affected Scenario C Benefit
Calculation in Final RIA
H. Poor Justification for the General Specification of Scenario
B in Final RIA
5. Error in the Volume Specification Affecting Benefits
Calculations in Two of Three Scenarios
6. Incorrect Use of the Production Levels That Do Not Account
for Increased Mortality When Calculating Benefits
7. Errors in Cost Calculations in the Final RIA
A. Production Levels Used To Calculate Costs and Benefits Differ
B. AMS Did Not Appropriately Consider the Costs to Aviaries That
Could Not Obtain Land
C. Production Shares Not Updated for Firm Exit
Non-Material Errors in the Final and Withdrawal RIAs
1. Other Transposition Errors
2. Weighting of WTP values
3. Different Depreciation Periods Are Used in Different Sections
of the Analysis
Summary
On January 19, 2017, the Agricultural Marketing Service (AMS)
promulgated the Organic Livestock and Poultry Practices Final Rule
(OLPP Rule), (82 FR 7042), and published the associated regulatory
impact analysis (Final RIA). AMS subsequently completed a rulemaking
that withdrew the OLPP Rule, (83 FR 10775) (Mar. 13, 2018), and
published the regulatory impact analysis in support of the withdrawal
(Withdrawal RIA). This Economic Analysis Report (Report) describes a
number of areas in which the Final RIA contained flaws in methodology
and calculations that materially affected AMS's economic analysis of
the costs and benefits of the OLPP Rule.
The Withdrawal RIA documented and sought to correct three of these
errors: The incorrect application of the discounting formula; the use
of an incorrect willingness to pay value for eggs produced under the
new open access requirements; and the incorrect application of a
depreciation treatment to the benefit calculations. This Report
identifies four additional categories of errors in the Final RIA that
were not detected or corrected during the rulemaking to withdraw the
OLPP Rule and were carried forward into the Withdrawal RIA. Those
errors are: Inconsistent or incorrect documentation of key calculation
variables; an error in the volume specification affecting benefits
calculations in two of three scenarios considered; the incorrect use of
production values that do not account for increased mortality loss in
the benefits calculations; and aspects of the cost calculations that
resulted in certain costs being ignored, underreported, or
inconsistently applied.
This Report also identifies additional issues related to the
erroneous depreciation methodology applied in the Final RIA. First, the
Final RIA contained errors in its treatment of depreciation of
benefits. The Withdrawal RIA attempted to correct the error; however,
it did not fully do so and therefore its final calculations were
inaccurate. The Final RIA included another error related to
depreciation of costs that was not previously identified and was
carried forward into the Withdrawal RIA.
In addition to the material errors, there were minor errors in the
Final RIA and the Withdrawal RIA. This Report describes three such
minor errors that do not have a material effect on cost and benefit
calculations.
Background
In April 2016 (81 FR 21956), AMS published the OLPP proposed rule
pertaining to certain aspects of organic livestock production certified
under the NOP. Among other provisions, the rule would have imposed
stricter requirements for producers of organic eggs to provide layers
with access to outdoor space and established stricter stocking density
requirements for broiler producers. In the preliminary regulatory
impact analysis (Preliminary RIA), AMS estimated that, despite the
added costs of complying with these requirements, all existing broiler
producers would become fully compliant with the new rule. On the other
hand, AMS expected the rule to cause a large portion of organic egg
producers to exit the industry. At the same time, because the organic
egg industry had experienced high rates of production growth in the
preceding years, AMS assumed that the organic egg industry would grow
substantially throughout the five year period between the rule's date
of publication and the date on which it required operations to become
fully compliant. For these reasons, both the Preliminary and Final RIAs
considered three alternative scenarios with different assumptions
regarding both firm exit and entry (i.e., industry growth). These
scenarios and underlying assumptions about firm exit and entry were
subsequently retained without change in the Withdrawal RIA.
As stated in the Final RIA (Passage 1, pages 6-7), these scenarios
are:
Scenario (A)--Full Compliance--``All producers remain in
the organic market; Organic layer and broiler populations continue
historical growth rates after the rule.''
Scenario (B)--Entry and Exit--``50 percent of organic
layer production in year 6 (2022) moves to the cage free market.
Organic layer and broiler populations continue historical growth rates
after the rule.''
Scenario (C)--Entry and Exit, No Non-Compliant Entry--``50
percent of organic layer production in year 6 (2022) moves to the cage
free market. There are no new entrants after publication of this rule
who cannot comply.''
Following public comment on the Preliminary RIA, AMS published the
OLPP Rule and Final RIA in the Federal Register in January 2017.
Between the Preliminary RIA and the Final RIA, AMS changed two key
assumptions. First, based on updated data, AMS
[[Page 22666]]
revised its expected growth rate of organic egg production upward from
2 percent to 12.7 percent, a change that would directly impact
Scenarios A and B, which assume continued industry growth.
Second, in the Preliminary RIA, AMS had previously applied a
depreciation treatment to both costs and benefits calculations whereby
the expected annual costs and benefits for egg producers were reduced
by one-thirteenth (1/13) each year until they reach zero in the
thirteenth year. This depreciation treatment differs from the commonly
understood accounting concept of depreciation that converts the loss in
value of a durable asset that is only infrequently purchased (i.e.,
tractor, barn, truck) to an annual cost. Instead, the depreciation
treatment used by AMS in the Preliminary RIA was intended to adjust the
costs of incumbent producers who were pre-committed to producing in the
organic industry (due to already owning a layer house) for the period
necessary to recover the value of their industry-specific assets. After
that point, the costs and benefits realized by these producers under
the OLPP Rule were no longer deemed to be attributable to the OLPP Rule
and were not included in the costs or benefits calculations of the
analysis. The justification for the application of this depreciation
treatment was that, as the value of a producer's industry-specific
assets become fully depreciated, that producer would no longer be
treated as pre-committed to the industry so that that producer's costs
and benefits were no longer, strictly speaking, due to the OLPP Rule
rather than the producer's independent decision to stay in the organic
market notwithstanding the OLPP Rule. In the Preliminary RIA, AMS based
its expected share of production that becomes fully depreciated each
year on Internal Revenue Service (IRS) schedules allowing for 13 years
of depreciation for specialized farm production structures (see Non-
Material Errors (3)). In the Final RIA, AMS removed the depreciation
treatment from its cost calculations, but not from its benefit
calculations. In the Withdrawal RIA, AMS acknowledged that it should
also have removed the depreciation treatment from its benefit
calculations as well.
In March 2018, AMS published the Withdrawal Rule, after notice-and-
comment, and the Withdrawal RIA. The Withdrawal RIA described three
errors in the Final RIA, which were: (1) The incorrect application of
the discounting formula, (2) the use of an incorrect willingness to pay
value for organic eggs produced under the OLPP Rule, and (3) the
application of depreciation to the values of calculated benefits. These
three errors pertained only to the calculation of benefits and did not
affect the analysis of costs described in the Final RIA. With the
Withdrawal RIA, AMS also published a spreadsheet that contained 10
pages that related Final RIA calculations to intermediary components of
the benefits calculation as modified in the Withdrawal RIA. This
document (Withdrawal Workbook) did not include detailed documentation
to allow simple cross-referencing of some key figures with the cost and
benefit values presented in the Final RIA or the Withdrawal RIA.
Appendix A provides that cross-referencing. Moreover, the Withdrawal
Workbook did not include new calculations for benefits that corrected
all three errors identified within the Withdrawal RIA, despite the
Withdrawal RIA presenting values intending to correct all identified
errors. For this reason, the benefit values in Table C of the
Withdrawal RIA do not correspond to the benefit values calculated in
sheets 6, 7, and 8 in the Withdrawal Workbook.
The OLPP Rule's egg producer requirements did not become fully
effective until the sixth year following the rule's publication to give
producers time to come into compliance.\1\ Both RIAs assumed that costs
of the OLPP Rule (other than administrative costs, which are ignored in
the analysis) would first be accrued in the third year following the
Rule's publication by producers who would need to acquire land to meet
the OLPP Rule's space requirements. The Final RIA assumed that benefits
would not accrue until the sixth year after publication, when full
compliance was required. These assumptions were retained in the
Withdrawal RIA. Since annual growth was assumed to be 12.7 percent in
both RIAs as well, firm entry and exit over the period between the
rule's year 1 publication and year 6 full compliance date would
potentially have a large effect on measured costs and benefits. In
general, differences in the assumptions regarding firm entry and exit
can dramatically affect the calculations of benefits and costs because
these values are tied to the number of eggs being produced each year.
Certain errors described by this Report pertain only to flaws in the
analysis of one or two of the three scenarios.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1\ To avoid confusion, this Report uses year 1 to refer to the
publication date and year 6 to the full compliance date. The Final
RIA and Withdrawal RIA use 2017 as year 1 and 2022 as year 6 since
the OLPP Rule was published in 2017, became effective one year
later, and had a five-year regulatory phase-in period.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Errors Detailed in This Report
Below are the descriptions and analyses of the errors found in the
Final RIA and the Withdrawal RIA.
1. Discounting Error in the Final RIA
As explained in the Withdrawal RIA, the Final RIA incorrectly
applied the discounting formula to the future benefits reported in the
Summary Table (pages 6-7) and Table 1 (pages 8-11). The OLPP Rule
considered costs and benefits over a period of 15 years. With
discounting practices used by economists, benefits or costs occurring
sooner are more valuable than those occurring later. To compare costs
or benefits across time, economists apply a discounting formula that
adjusts the value of future benefits and costs to their present value
equivalent. Guidance to Federal agencies \2\ describes the rationale
for discounting and methods of its application in detail. Specifically,
to convert future costs and benefits to their present value, they are
to be multiplied by 1/(1 + r)t where t is the number of years in the
future that the benefits or costs occur and r is the discount rate,
which the guidance recommends to be applied at the 3 and 7 percent
rates. Benefits or costs that have been adjusted in this way are called
(discounted) present values.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\2\ Office of Management and Budget Circular A-4, dated
September 17, 2003, provides guidance on best practices associated
with cost-benefit analysis to Federal agencies undertaking
rulemaking.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
A total present value of benefits (TB) can then be calculated by
simply summing the present values of benefits across years. Denoting
the value of benefits in year t as Bt, the correct formula for TB over
the 15 years considered in the rule is:
[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP23AP20.016
[[Page 22667]]
However, in the Final RIA, an incorrect formula was used to calculate
total benefits. In the case where r is 3 percent, that formula, denoted
TBIncorrect,r=0.03, was:
[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP23AP20.017
In this case, the exponent in the denominator for all periods after the
second year was incorrectly set to 2.
A different error was present for the total benefits formula in the
case where r is 7 percent, denoted
TBIncorrect,r=7[percnt] below as:
[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP23AP20.018
In this case, the exponent in the denominator was incorrectly set to 1
for all periods.
This Report agrees with both the Withdrawal RIA's assessment and
correction of the discount rate error in the benefits calculations of
the Final RIA.
2. Willingness To Pay Value Was Too High in the Final RIA
The Final RIA contained an error that made the willingness to pay
(WTP) value used in the benefits calculations too high. Specifically,
the Final RIA drew upon an inappropriate estimate for the value of eggs
produced with the new outdoor access requirements. This error was
identified and corrected in the Withdrawal RIA.
The Final RIA drew primarily upon a 2013 article by Yan Heng,
Hikaru Hanawa Peterson, and Xianghong Li involving a choice experiment
conducted on 924 surveyed consumers.\3\ In the experiment, consumers
were asked to choose between eggs that differ in terms of the growing
conditions of the laying hens. Price and growing conditions were
adjusted across choices to optimize the ability to identify consumers'
value for eggs produced under different growing conditions. The study
applied a stated preference method of estimating the WTP for eggs that
now meet the new outdoor access requirement in the OLPP Rule. In brief,
the Final RIA focused on the article's text (Passage 2, page 419)
stating:
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\3\ The article is titled ``Consumer Attitudes toward Farm-
Animal Welfare: The Case of Laying Hens'' and published in the
Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics,38(3):418-434 (2013).
Our estimates suggest that the majority of consumers are willing
to pay an average premium of $0.21 to $0.49 per dozen for eggs
produced in a cage-free environment with outdoor access or without
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
induced molting.
Based on this text, the Final RIA assigned a premium value per egg to
the outdoor access characteristic of $0.49 on the high side and of
$0.21 on the low side. However, the Withdrawal RIA notes that under
existing rules, organic eggs are already required to be produced cage-
free. The Withdrawal RIA notes that the actual benefit attributable to
the OLPP Rule should be comprised of only the portion of the WTP
described by Heng, Peterson, and Li (2013) that may be ascribed to the
addition of new outdoor access requirements to existing organic egg
production requirements.
Table 8 (``Statistics of Simulated WTP Distributions'') of the
Heng, Petersen, and Li (2013) study provides estimates of the WTP for
eggs produced by hens under the new outdoor access requirements
(Passage 3, page 429), explaining that in a subsample of consumers that
received additional information regarding the environmental benefits of
cage-free systems and outdoor access:
89% (59%) of respondents were willing to pay a premium for eggs
from hens given outdoor access (more space), with a mean premium of
$0.25. In [a second] subsample that did not receive the additional
information, the mean premium for outdoor access (more space) was
lower, at $0.16, with 81% (43%) of those willing to pay a premium.
To correct for this error, the Withdrawal RIA therefore replaced the
Final RIA's high WTP estimate of $0.49 and its low WTP estimate of
$0.21 with new high and low WTP estimates of $0.25 and $0.16 (with all
dollar values referring to price per dozen eggs).
This Report finds that the Withdrawal RIA corrected the WTP value
error in an appropriate manner. We note in (2) of our Non-Material
Errors section, however, that the correction contained a minor error
that did not have a material effect on the calculations.
3. Depreciation Errors
A. Depreciation of Future Benefits Error in the Final RIA
The Preliminary RIA applied the depreciation treatment to both the
benefit and costs calculations. The Final RIA applied the depreciation
treatment only to the benefits calculations, not to costs. The Final
RIA (Passage 4, pages 111-112) states that:
For each cohort, AMS applied the full compliance costs for each
year after the rule must be fully implemented. These recurrent costs
are incurred through year 15, relative to the without-regulation
baseline. Given the uncertainty in these cost estimates and
forecasting impacts in the organic egg market, AMS is presenting
estimates without depreciation to capture the full range of
potential impacts. . . . . While AMS is presenting the costs
associated with this methodology as the primary costs estimates, we
discuss the rationale for an alternative methodology based on
linearly reducing costs over the depreciation time period for
poultry houses.
The following description of applying the depreciation to the
cost estimates would yield a lower cost estimate. This also assumes
that costs only accrue to legacy organic producers. . . . . [italics
added]
The ``alternative methodology'' text refers to the method of applying
the depreciation treatment while computing cost calculations. The ``AMS
is presenting estimates without depreciation'' text indicates that
costs calculations in the Final RIA did not incorporate the
depreciation treatment as they had in the Preliminary RIA. Finally, the
``assumes that costs only accrue to legacy organic producers'' text
explains that the inclusion of the discussion regarding depreciation
treatment as an alternative rationale was motivated by the specific
assumption that costs and benefits only arise from the actions of
legacy producers and only to those producers until their capital
investments under the prior regulatory regime were fully depreciated.
[[Page 22668]]
Notwithstanding this discussion, the Final RIA states in footnotes
92 and 94 that the depreciation treatment was being applied to benefits
calculations because it had also been applied to costs. Specifically,
Footnote 92 (Passage 5, page 97) states:
The 13 year period accounts for the time needed to fully
depreciate layer houses. We use a 13 year timeframe to align with
the methodology used to calculate the costs, below [in footnote 94].
In short, despite concluding at pages 111-112 of the Final RIA that it
would not apply the depreciation treatment to costs, footnote 92
explained AMS's application of the depreciation treatment to its
benefits calculations in the Final RIA as a way to be consistent with
an application of the depreciation treatment to costs.
The Preliminary RIA included cost and benefits calculations in
which the 13-year depreciation treatment was both applied and not
applied. For instance, Table 9 (pages 126-127) shows layer costs as
falling in a range each year. The upper limit to the range is constant
and reflected the estimated costs without the depreciation treatment.
For layers, this is $28,160,000. The lower limit to the range is the
depreciated value and it falls by one-thirteenth of the $28,160,000, or
$2,166,000, each year.
The Final RIA's removal of the depreciation treatment from costs
appears to have been intended to be associated with its same removal
from the benefits calculations as well. The Withdrawal RIA (Passage 6,
page 11) states that:
In initial drafts of the OLPP final rule RIA, AMS applied a
straight-line reduction in both costs and benefits over time to
reflect the economic life of egg and broiler structures. Both
benefits and costs declined every year as a fraction of the industry
structures became fully depreciated and reached the end of their
economic lifetimes.
Footnotes 92 and 94 of the Final RIA show that the depreciation
treatment was not removed from the benefits calculations in that
analysis. The Withdrawal RIA (Passage 7, page 11) states as much in the
text:
Costs were instead estimated to be constant over time, but
benefits were still straight line reduced over time. The same
reasoning should have been applied to the benefits to make the
calculation of costs and benefits consistent.
The Withdrawal RIA calculated new values for benefits without the
straight-line depreciation treatment applied. This Report concurs with
the Withdrawal RIA's assessment that the Final RIA contained an error
in its inconsistent application of the depreciation treatment to
benefits but not costs. However, as we describe in Section 3.B to
follow, the Withdrawal RIA does not fully address that error.
B. Depreciation Treatment Not Fully Removed From Benefits Calculations
in the Withdrawal RIA
The Withdrawal RIA attempts to correct the depreciation error in
the Final RIA by removing the treatment of depreciation from the
calculation of benefits, but it failed to do so entirely.\4\ This new
benefit calculation has the following five steps: \5\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\4\ Other sections to this Report evaluate the treatment of
depreciation, production growth, and firm exit from the industry in
their totality.
\5\ Note that these steps are similar to those described in
Footnote 94 of the Final RIA with three key differences. First,
straight-line depreciation treatment is not applied. Second,
discounting is applied. Third, total discounted payments are
converted to their annual benefit values.
i. Estimate the number of eggs produced that would newly have
outdoor access, as defined by the OLPP Rule, after the Rule takes
effect in year 6 (Ey6);
ii. Multiply Ey6 by the WTP for the new outdoor access to obtain
the benefit value by year;
iii. Apply time discounting to each year's benefits (at either
the 3 or 7 percent rate);
iv. Sum the benefits over years 6 to 13; and
v. Convert the summed discounted benefits to an annual benefit
over 15 yearly periods.\6\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\6\ This conversion was done using the Microsoft Payment
function. The formula for the annual benefit, AB, is a function
based on r; the discount rate, N; the number of years (i.e., 15);
and TB, the summed discounted benefits. The value is given as: AB =
(TB x r)/(1-(1+r)-N).
The number of eggs projected to be produced after the Rule took effect
depends on which of the three scenarios, described in the Introduction
to this Report, is being considered. Several omissions in the
Preliminary and Final RIAs stymie the independent review and
replication of key figures provided in the Withdrawal RIA and the
Withdrawal Workbook to this Report. Those concerns are described in
Section 5 of this Report. To assess the Withdrawal RIA corrections, one
can recover the values for Ey6 in the Withdrawal Workbook by dividing
the year one benefit values by $0.21 (in the low case) and $0.49 (in
the high case). Table 1 provides the Ey6 values and the location where
they are stated for each scenario.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\7\ Sheet 8 erroneously contains the same values as Sheet 7 for
the benefits in its top half. From its bottom half, the production
level of 89,361,091 can be inferred by dividing the first year
undiscounted benefits value of $18,765,829.11 by 0.21.
Table 1--Production Estimates in the Withdrawal Workbook
------------------------------------------------------------------------
Withdrawal workbook
Scenario E location
------------------------------------------------------------------------
Scenario A..................... 355,289,326 Sheet 6--Production
with newly acquired
outdoor access.
Scenario B..................... 97,708,552 Sheet 7--Production
with newly acquired
outdoor access.
Scenario C..................... 89,361,091 Sheet 8--Inferred from
Values of Undiscounted
Benefits.\7\
------------------------------------------------------------------------
The Withdrawal RIA generates benefit values (i.e., those realized
in year 6 of the analysis period when the requirement for full
compliance takes effect) based on the WTP values of $0.16 and $0.25 per
dozen eggs. The benefits used in the Withdrawal RIA should be constant
across all years and continue into year 14 and 15 since they are no
longer subject to the depreciation treatment. However, in the
implementation of its corrections, the Withdrawal RIA used the year 6
benefit value from the Final RIA to determine the constant annual
benefit value with the depreciation treatment removed. Since that year
6 value incorporated 5 periods of depreciation treatment pursuant to
the erroneous depreciation treatment, the value is five-thirteenths (or
38.4 percent) less than the value the Withdrawal RIA should have used.
For this reason, while this Report agrees with the Withdrawal RIA's
assessment of the Final RIA's error in depreciating benefits as
described in Section 3(A), it finds that the Withdrawal RIA retained a
benefits calculation affected by the flawed application of the
depreciation treatment methodology and thus failed to fully correct for
that error.
C. Depreciation Treatment Not Fully Removed From Scenario A Cost
Calculations in the Withdrawal RIA
Although the Final RIA stated that it did not apply the
depreciation treatment to the cost calculations, an artifact of the
[[Page 22669]]
depreciation treatment actually was retained in some of its cost
calculations. Table 15 on page 116 of the Final RIA reported annual
costs for Scenario A. Layer houses were assumed to be comprised of the
same ratio composition as described (i.e., 70 percent aviaries, 30
percent non-aviaries). Table 15 of the Final RIA shows that for layer
houses greater than 4-years old, costs are $3.81 million in year 3
(representing one-time land-acquisition costs) and $24.29 million from
years 6 to 15; for 2-years old layer houses, costs are $6.62 million
from years 6 to 15; for 1-year old layer houses, costs are $13.23
million. Page 111 of the Final RIA assumed that 4-year old houses
represent 64 percent of production facilities, 2-year old houses
represent 24 percent of production facilities, and 1-year old houses
represent 12 percent of production facilities. Underlying AMS
calculations (described in Section 6 of this Report) show that the sum
of total (physical) costs and lost revenue is $55.13 million under
Scenario A. Table 2 shows the decomposition of producers' costs to the
OLPP Rule by age of operation.
Table 2--Decomposition of Producers' Costs to the OLPP Rule by Age of House
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Years 6 to 15
Age of house Share of Year 3 costs costs
houses (%) (million) (million)
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Older than 4-year-old houses.................................... 64 $3.81 $24.29
2-year-old houses............................................... 24 $0 $6.62
1-year-old houses............................................... 12 $0 $13.32
-----------------------------------------------
Total....................................................... 100 $3.81 $44.13
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
AMS's removal of the depreciation treatment from its costs
calculations in the Final RIA implied that the age of facilities should
have no bearing on annualized calculations of costs. However, in Table
15 of the Final RIA, the depreciation treatment was applied for four
years for the 64 percent of houses that were more than 4 years old.
Rather than using $35.29 million (= 64% x $55.13 million) for this
class of houses, the number is $24.43 million (= 64% x (9/13) x $55.13
million).\8\ Table 15 applied no similar depreciation to 2- and 1-year
old houses whose values correspond to their respective share of the
market multiplied by $55.13 million. The calculation for the 4-year old
houses in Table 15 reflects that the depreciation treatment was not
fully removed from the cost analysis.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\8\ The $24.43 Million figure is stated in cell F29 of the
``Stay in Organic'' Worksheet of B-Layer, along with intermediary
steps in the equations. The $24.29 Million figure in Table 2 is
stated in the page 1 of the Withdrawal Workbook. This Report cannot
explain the discrepancy in values.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
This Report finds that the Withdrawal RIA's downward adjustment of
costs by 4/13th for houses that are four years old or greater was
inappropriate because, first, it applies to all costs (i.e., feed,
labor, etc.), not just the industry-specific assets that depreciate
over time and, second, it is inconsistent with the ordinary
depreciation of assets applied elsewhere in the analysis (see Final
RIA, page 103). In this case, the downward adjustment reduced layer
costs by 18.2 percent for Scenario A.
4. Inconsistent or Incorrect Documentation of Underlying Assumptions in
the Final RIA
This section notes instances where the Final RIA contained
conflicting or omitted data on key figures used in calculations and
inconsistent descriptions of certain scenarios regarding entry and
exit. Many of these omissions or inconsistencies interact with errors
previously discussed in this Report. This Report finds that, due to
these inconsistencies and omissions, a knowledgeable external reviewer
would have had substantial difficulty replicating the key findings of
the Final RIA.\9\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\9\ OMB Circular A-4 providing guidance on Federal rule-making
states (page 17): A good analysis should be transparent and your
results must be reproducible. You should clearly set out the basic
assumptions, methods, and data underlying the analysis and discuss
the uncertainties associated with the estimates. A qualified third
party reading the analysis should be able to understand the basic
elements of your analysis and the way in which you developed your
estimates.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
A. Baseline Egg Production Values Used in Calculations Differ From
Those Described in Text
In the Final RIA, AMS assumed the organic egg industry would
continue at its historical growth of an average of 12.7 percent per
year during the 6 years following the publication of the OLPP Rule
until full implementation of the Rule in 2022. Table 3 of the Final RIA
(page 46) states the baseline quantities of 325.83M doz. eggs in 2016,
367.21M doz. in 2017, and 667.63M doz. in 2022. The Withdrawal Workbook
projected that 390.83M doz. eggs would be produced in 2017. Footnote 89
(page 96) and Footnote 94 (page 97) of the Final RIA alternatively list
710.58M doz. in 2022. Both Table 3 of the Final RIA and Footnotes 89
and 94 of the Final RIA reflect the assumption of 12.7 percent annual
industry growth, but because the two sets of numbers have different
starting values, the Final RIA baseline production figures in Table 3
on page 46 are 6.4 percent lower than the baseline production figures
used in the calculations in footnotes 89 and 96 in every year, without
any explanation for that difference. The 390.83M doz. eggs figure in
the Withdrawal Workbook appears to be based on 14,087,500 organic
laying hens reported in the AMS Weekly USDA Certified Organic Poultry
and Eggs Report first reported for November 15th 2016.\10\ In each
period, organic laying hens produced 24.77 dozen eggs per year, a
figure that is not documented explicitly in the Final RIA (See Section
4.B).\11\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\10\ The 14,087,500 figure is, itself, rounded to 14,000,000 in
the analysis.
\11\ One can only infer the 24.77 dozen eggs per year value from
the Withdrawal Workbook.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
This Report notes that reproduction of the Final RIA calculations
would be very difficult without the actual baseline production estimate
and this number would be very difficult to ascertain from the Final RIA
in light of the inconsistent figures and omissions described above.
B. Baseline Egg Production Figures Used in Final RIA Differ From Those
in Cited Market News Reports
Page 17 of the Final RIA (Passage 8) states:
In April 2016, AMS Market News reported 14 million organic layers
currently in production.
[[Page 22670]]
This statement is incorrect. AMS Market News reported a count of
11,350,500 organic layers in each of the four reporting weeks in April
of 2016 in its ``Weekly USDA Certified Organic Poultry and Eggs''
reports. It was not until November 14, 2016, that the AMS Market News
report began reporting 14,087,500 organic layers.\12\ The highest level
of organic eggs recorded as being produced between April 2016 and
January 2017 was 207,497 30-dozen cases, or 6,224,910 dozen per week.
Based on 52.143 weeks per year, this corresponds to 324,584,3593 dozen
egg produced per year for an average of 276.49 eggs, or 23.0406 dozen,
per laying hen per year. Separately, the National Agricultural
Statistics Service (NASS) Chickens and Eggs Summary for 2015, which
includes organic and conventional eggs, lists the average number of
eggs per layer as 276, or 23 dozen, in 2015 and 276.6, or 23.05 dozen,
in 2016. In contrast, based on AMS's calculation in Tables 6, 7, and 8
of Withdrawal Workbook,\13\ AMS assumed, without explanation, that the
average annual dozen eggs laid per bird was 24.7708. This higher
production value increased the estimated number of eggs produced by
7.51 percent over the estimate in the contemporaneous Market News
Report.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\12\ The AMS Market News report adjusts organic egg production
figures only every month or so.
\13\ Specifically, 24.7708 Eggs Per Layer is the ratio of
``Eggs'' to ``Layers #'s'' for each year except for year 4. As
explained in the section on Non-material Errors (1.B), the year 4
Eggs value likely reflects a transposition error.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
This Report finds that the use of the 24.7708 dozen eggs-per-layer
assumption was inappropriate for two reasons. First, the data source of
egg-per-layer value used is poorly documented and significantly exceeds
other readily available data collected by USDA at the national level.
Second, it deviates from the AMS Weekly Report data relied upon in the
Final RIA for the layer numbers. It is generally considered a best
practice to use a single, consistent data set because doing so limits
the possible ways that biases arising from methodological differences
and data-collection error may influence the analysis.
C. Separate Descriptions of Scenario C in the Final RIA Do Not Match
The Final RIA calculates costs and benefits under three sets of
assumptions regarding the entry of operations to the industry (i.e.,
industry growth at a 12.7 percent rate in the five years preceding the
full compliance date) and the exit of operations when firms must become
compliant in year 6. This Report previously described Scenario C based
on descriptions from pages 6 and 7 of the Final RIA. However, pages 98
and 118 of the Final RIA include an alternative description of Scenario
C (labeled hereafter as Scenario C.2, to distinguish it from the
description of Scenario C described in the Summary Table on pages 6-7
in the Final RIA) that has an important difference affecting the cost
and benefit calculations applicable to that scenario. Specifically,
Scenario C.2 is described on page 98 (Passage 9) as assuming that:
. . . 50 percent of current production would exit the organic
market in 2022 and that there would be no new entrants until that
time. [italics added]
Page 118 seems to reflect the same description stating:
We base costs on . . . the layer population in 2017, and no new
entrants to the organic egg market during the implementation period
for this rule. [italics added]
However, page 118 later states that:
In addition, we expect that any producers who cannot comply with
this rule will not enter the organic egg market during the
implementation period.
The page 98 quote assuming ``no new entrants until [2022]'' and the
page 118 quote assuming ``no new entrants . . . during the
implementation period [through 2022]'' support the description in
Scenario C.2. The second quote on page 118, suggests, however, that
entry continues but only by compliant producers. Page 7 of the Final
RIA describes Scenario C similarly to the description in the second
quote on page 118, which suggests that entry (i.e., growth) continues
but that ``there are no new entrants after publication of this rule who
cannot comply'' with the OLPP Rule. The he ``who cannot comply''
language is superfluous unless there are also entrants who can comply.
If entry (i.e., growth) continues as assumed by Scenario C, 711 million
eggs are projected to be produced in year 6 and the share of production
that is already compliant exceeds 50 percent. If no entry occurs as
assumed by Scenario C.2 (i.e., no growth), 390M eggs are produced in
year 6 and the share of production that is already compliant is less
than 50 percent. As we discuss in Section 5, cost and benefit
calculations for Scenario C depend only on the number of non-compliant
producers that become compliant as a result of the OLPP Rule in year 6.
If a large number of compliant producers enter the industry after the
rule is announced, then the share of industry that is non-compliant in
year 6 becomes smaller. In Section 5, this Report describes how
Scenario C implies that less than 50 percent of operations are non-
compliant in year 6 so that the 50 percent share of producers that AMS
assumes will remain in the industry after the OLPP Rule takes effect
would all already be compliant. For this reason, the discrepancy
between the Scenario C and Scenario C.2 descriptions has a direct
impact on cost and benefit calculations.
This Report notes that confusion over the exact assumptions
involving Scenario C is likely to have prevented external reviewers
from replicating key cost and benefit calculations, especially when
this problem occurs in conjunction with other documentation errors
surrounding baseline production values.
D. Number of Eggs With New Outdoor Access Not Stated for Two of Three
Scenarios
Neither pages 97 and 98 of the Final RIA nor any other section of
the Final RIA states the number of eggs that are subject to the OLPP
Rule (Ey6) in Scenario B and C. While the Ey6 value of 97,708,552 for
Scenario B was subsequently provided later in the Withdrawal Workbook,
the Scenario C value of 89,361,091 is not explicitly stated and can
only be inferred from calculations in the tables. See Sections 5.G and
the footnote to Table 1 of this Report for discussion. While these
omissions do not represent errors in the calculations unto themselves,
they would have, especially in conjunction with other errors mentioned
in this section, severely hampered the ability of external reviewers to
replicate and examine key calculations regarding both the benefit and
cost calculations of the Final RIA.
E. Benefits Values Reported in Summary Tables Do Not Match the Text
The Summary Table (pages 6-7) and Table 1 (pages 8-11) of the Final
RIA present benefit calculations that do not match the descriptions of
those calculation on pages 97 and 98 (Passage 10). Specifically,
Scenario A benefits:
``. . . range between $13.77 million to $ 32.1 million annually
with a mean value of $23 million over a 15-year period.''
Scenario B benefits:
``. . . range from $3.79 million to $8.84 million per year''
Scenario C benefits:
``. . . range from $6.93 million to $16.17 million per year.''
In contrast, the Summary Table and Table 1 list Scenario A benefits at
$16.3 to $49.5 million, Scenario B benefits at
[[Page 22671]]
$4.5 to $13.8 million, and Scenario C benefits at $4.1 to $12.4
million.
The Summary Table and Table 1 show the sum of benefits to which
discounting (which had been done improperly) and the depreciation
treatment have been applied and which was then converted to an
annualized benefit using the Microsoft Excel Payment (PMT) function
(see footnote 6). The page 97 text, however, presents the average
annual benefits to which the depreciation treatment but not discounting
had been applied. Also, the page 97 values do not annualize the total
benefit using the Payment function, but instead sum the yearly benefits
and then divide that sum by the total number of years considered, 15.
The Final RIA does not present the benefit values stated in the Summary
Table and Table 1 elsewhere in the document, nor does it describe the
function used to convert total benefits to an annualized figure. These
discrepancies would likely have prevented a knowledgeable reader from
independently replicating the AMS calculations.
F. Costs Estimates for Scenario A in Final RIA Text Are Inconsistent
Page 110 of the Final RIA (Passage 11) states:
For the organic egg sector, AMS estimates that the costs of this
rule will average $15 million to $21.9 million annually, over 15
years, if all producers comply (the discounted annualized estimated
costs are $24.7 million to $27.5).
These costs align with the cost figures in the Summary Table and Table
1 for Scenario A only. Note that across all the scenarios considered,
the discounted annualized estimated costs of the broiler rule are
unchanged at $3.541 million at the 3 percent discount rate and $4.092
million at the 7 percent discount rate, figures reflected in the last
two columns of Sheet 1 in the Withdrawal Workbook. That same sheet
shows that the sum of the layer and broiler cost components of the rule
is $31.036 million at the 3 percent level and $28.699 million at the 7
percent level. These figures correspond to the Summary Table (pages 6-
7), Table 1 (pages 8-11), and Table 15 (page 116) of the Final RIA.\14\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\14\ Similarly, page 114 also states that ``[i]n summary, the
average annual costs for the organic poultry sector are estimated to
range from $17.4 to $24.7 million annually over 15 years.''
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
In contrast, pages 111-112 (Passage 12) of the Final RIA states:
If all currently certified organic egg producers comply with
this rule and the organic production continues to grow at 12.7
percent each year, we estimated that the annual cost of the rule is
$32.3 million ($17 million at 7 percent discount; 24.2 million at 3
percent discount.)
The preface indicates that this passage also describes Scenario A but
the figures do not match those previously stated, any of the figures
found in Summary Table, Table 1, or Table 15 of the Final RIA, or the
figures presented in the first three sheets of the Withdrawal
Workbook.\15\ \16\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\15\ The Withdrawal RIA made no corrections to the cost
calculations in the Final RIA. For this reason, an error in the
Final RIA cost calculations extends into the Withdrawal RIA as well.
\16\ Pages 121-23 of the Final RIA consider Scenarios B and C
together, with Table 16 (page 122) corresponding to Scenario C and
Table 17 (page 123) corresponding to Scenario B.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
G. Transposition Error Likely Affected Scenario C Benefit Calculation
in Final RIA
The number of eggs used in Scenario C in the Final RIA should
likely have been 88,822,332 rather than 89,361,091. The value
88,822,332 is one-eighth of the total number of eggs produced after 5
years of growth at the 12.7 percent rate, or \1/4\ x (24.77083335 x
14,343,051) where 24.77083335 is the number of dozen eggs produced per
layer annually and 14,343,051 is half of 28,686,102, the number of
layers after 5 years of growth. The incorrect value of 89,361,091 (=
\1/4\ x 357,444,364) eggs used in Scenario C corresponds with the
incorrect substitution of 14,430,050 for 14,343,051. The italicized
material suggests where a transposition error likely occurred, an error
that carried through from the Final RIA to the Withdrawal RIA.\17\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\17\ The Excel File titled ``C-OLPP All Costs Benefits FINAL''
contained the sheet ``Benefits--cage-free no entry'' forming some of
the calculations in Sheet 8 of the Withdrawal Workbook. In this
Excel file, the value of 357,444,364 eggs did not have an underlying
formula or source associated with it, but the 89,361,091 value for
the number of eggs that entered the benefits equation was defined as
\1/4\ of that value.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
H. Poor Justification for the General Specification of Scenario B in
Final RIA
Scenario B in the Final RIA made the assumption that between the
time the rule was published in 2017, and five years later, when full
compliance was required, industry production would grow at a 12.7
percent annual growth rate. This rate predicted industry growth of 81.8
percent from year 1 to year 6.\18\ Then, scenario B assumes that after
5 years of such growth, 50 percent of firms would exit the organic egg
industry. Because the ratio of producer types stays constant, the
scenario implies that half of the producers who entered the industry
after the rule was published in year 1 would then leave the industry at
the compliance date. Under a modest assumed level of industry growth,
this specification might be inconsequential. However, given the high
assumed rate of production growth (81.8 percent), this specification
implies that a production volume equal to 40.6 percent of the baseline
production level both enters and departs the organic egg industry over
the span of five years with full knowledge of the regulatory
requirements expected to cause the departure of half of the market upon
the compliance date. Page 47 of the Final RIA seems to preclude this
possibility (Passage 13), stating:
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\18\ This rate of growth is substantially larger than the 2
percent growth rate assumed in the preliminary RIA and is explained
in footnote 131 on page 126 of the Final RIA as reflecting new data.
After publication of the rule, AMS projects continued entry into
the organic egg market (see Table 3). The implementation dates of
the rule as drafted would give those operations--certified after the
publication of the rule but prior to 3 years after publication--5
years to comply. This is intended to provide additional time to
producers who had intended to enter organic production near the time
this rule is published to prepare land to meet the organic
requirements (the required preparation time lasts three years).
Given that the proposal was published early in 2016, the majority of
new entrants from publication (2017) until three years later (2020)
would be aware of the new requirements and construct facilities that
comply with the outdoor space requirements. Because there is no
economic rationale for a producer to incur the licensing and
construction expenses associated with organic production, only to be
out of compliance within a few years, late entrants into the market
are assumed to comply. However, in the cost estimates below, AMS
considered that there may be new entrants up until full
implementation for layers and that there may be costs to these
entrants. We believe this could significantly overestimate the
costs, but are providing this to capture a range of potential
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
outcomes given uncertainties in the underlying assumption.
In Passage 13, AMS states that it assumes that all late entrants (i.e.,
those entering the industry after the rule is published) would be
compliant with the new rule because there is ``no economic rationale''
to believe that they would not be. However, by allowing for growth in
non-compliant operations, particularly aviaries, within the underlying
costs calculations, AMS assumed that such firms continue to enter. The
implication of AMS's later statement that the inclusion of ``new [non-
compliant] entrants . . . could significantly overestimate the costs''
would only have the effect of increasing costs in the final
calculations is misleading because a higher number of non-compliant
operations moving into compliance
[[Page 22672]]
increases the size of the estimated benefits. Within the structure of
AMS cost and benefit calculations, operations that are already
compliant with the rule in year 6 do not create have new costs to
become compliant, nor do they create any new benefits. As described in
Section 5, if all entrants to the industry after year 1 are compliant
with the new outdoor access requirement, then greater than 50 percent
of operations are already compliant in year 6 when AMS assumes that the
50 percent of presumably non-compliant operations leave the industry.
This suggests that there would be no new benefits and no new costs if
only compliant firms enter the industry before year 6 but after the
OLPP Rule's publication.
Given the costs and time for firms to enter the organic industry,
this Report finds that AMS's assumption that non-compliant operations
continue to enter the industry in the period after the OLPP Rule's
publication date but before its compliance date is not well-justified.
5. Error in the Volume Specification Affecting Benefits Calculations in
Two of Three Scenarios
In the Final RIA, AMS stated that the outdoor access requirement
established by the OLPP Rule for organic egg production is a ``credence
good'' because it is a characteristic that cannot be independently
verified by the consumer at the time of consumption and therefore
requires trust in a label to ascertain that the quality characteristic
is present. AMS did not specify how consumers of compliant eggs know
that the layers of these eggs have open access to the outdoors, whether
operations advertise their eggs as having that characteristic, or
whether consumers of such eggs pay a premium (above the ordinary
organic premium) for eggs with this characteristic. The presence of
such premiums would likely affect the content of the RIA. Regardless of
these mechanisms, AMS assumed that only organic eggs that did not
previously have the outdoor access production characteristic and now
acquired it as a result of the OLPP Rule would generate new benefits
for consumers.
On page 27 of the Final RIA (Passage 14), AMS wrote:
In response to the descriptions in public comment, AMS is
modifying the estimated proportion of organic operations that have
adequate land to comply with this rule. In the proposed rule, we
estimated this could be 50 percent of organic egg production. As
discussed above, AMS is assuming that all aviary operations, which
account for an estimated 70 percent of organic egg production, would
need to acquire additional land. Based on public comments, we are
also projecting that a portion, 17 percent, of single-story (non-
aviary) operations, which account for an estimated 5 percent of all
organic egg production, would also need to acquire additional land
because they may not have two barn footprints of outdoor space due
to various conditions specific to the operation.
Scenarios A, B, and C specify that growth occurs in the industry at a
12.7 percent rate from year 1 to year 6.\19\ Scenario C (but not
Scenario C.2) indicates that the proportion of facilities of each type
in the industry changes as the industry grows. The construction of
Scenarios A and B, however, strongly suggests that there is no change
in the proportions of production facilities of each type through year
6. Page 27 (Passage 15) then states:
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\19\ Non-aviary systems account for 30 percent of production.
One-sixth of these producers (16.67 percent) is 5 percent of all
production.
In summary, AMS assumes that operations representing 75 percent
of organic egg production could incur costs for purchasing and
maintaining additional land to comply with the outdoor stocking
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
density requirement.
This statement, in which the outdoor stocking density requirement
refers to the new requirements for outdoor access under the OLPP Rule,
implies that if the proportions of all operations of each type remain
in production and no firms exit the industry (as Scenario A indicates),
then 75 percent of current organic egg production will gain new outdoor
access as a result of the rule.
Scenario A assumes that all producers become compliant. The Final
RIA calculates benefits for Scenario A by multiplying the WTP values by
one-half of year 6 production. In this case, multiplying production by
50 percent is likely a correction for the proportion of existing
production that is already compliant. If so, this proportion likely
reflects the Preliminary RIA's lower assumed proportion of production
occurring under aviary systems. The Preliminary RIA states (Passage 16,
page 115):
For this analysis, we assumed that pasture housing, floor litter
housing and slatted/mesh floor housing systems collectively account
for 50 percent of organic egg production and either currently comply
with the outdoor space requirements or have the land available to
comply with the proposed outdoor stocking rate without significant
changes to the number of birds or facilities.
In the Preliminary RIA, AMS assumed that 50 percent of production was
from non-aviary type facilities (i.e., pasture housing, floor litter
housing, and pit litter housing systems) and already compliant with the
OLPP Rule and that the other 50 percent was of the aviary type and not
compliant. Under these assumptions for Scenario A (Full Compliance),
the share of production that would acquire new outdoor access and
provide new benefits to consumers was 50 percent of production.
In the Final RIA, AMS altered this assumption and instead assumed
that 30 percent of production was from non-aviaries (with only 25
percent of total production being already compliant) and that the other
70 percent of production was from non-compliant aviary operations.
Under these new assumptions, 75 percent of production would provide new
benefits to consumers because that is the share of production not
already in compliance with the OLPP Rule before it takes effect. For
this reason, this Report finds that calculations in the Final RIA that
assume that new benefits only arise from 50 percent of the organic egg
produced in year 6 in Scenario A are inconsistent with assumptions
stated elsewhere.
Scenario B assumes that the industry and production grow at the
12.7 percent rate annually between year 1 and year 6 and that 50
percent of current production exits the industry in year 6 when the
rule becomes effective.\20\ Page 27 of the Final RIA (Passage 15)
indicates that 75 percent of production must incur costs to become
compliant with the open access requirement. If the 50 percent of
production that exit the organic market are noncompliant producers,
then 25 percent of production will have been noncompliant, become
compliant as a result of the rule, and now gained new outdoor access.
Scenario B calculates benefits based on 25 percent of year 6 production
gaining new outdoor access (which are subsequently multiplied by the
WTP value). This Report assesses those calculations as being accurate
given the description of assumptions made on the composition of
production with regard to compliance.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\20\ In the Withdrawal Workbook, AMS presented tables that
projected future volumes based on a 12.7 growth rate for the entire
15-year period considered in the analysis. The higher egg volume
projections after year six, however, had no bearing on the actual
calculations of costs and benefits.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
As described previously, Scenario C assumes that 50 percent of
current production exits the industry in year 6. Between year 1 and
year 6, growth was assumed to occur at the 12.7 percent rate but no
non-compliant producers were expected to enter the industry. To find
the amount of production by incumbent firms that now provide new
benefits to consumers, let QALL be all producers in year one
and 0.75 x QALL
[[Page 22673]]
be all non-compliant producers in year one. If production grows by 12.7
percent for 5 years, production in year 6 is 1.818 x QALL
(=1.127[supcaret]5 x Q). Of these producers, there are still 0.75 x
QALL non-compliant producers in the industry (i.e., the same
number of non-compliant producers from year one). Subsequentially, the
remaining 1.068 x QALL are all compliant.
If half of production exits the industry under Scenario C, then
0.91 x QALL leave the industry. Presumably, only non-
compliant producers leave the industry in year 6. This implies that all
of the non-compliant production from year 1 leaves the industry (0.75 x
QALL) along with an additional 0.16 x QALL of
production that is already compliant. Since already compliant
operations that remain in the industry do not generate any new
benefits, no new benefits are created under the assumed conditions of
Scenario C. In the Final RIA, however, AMS based its benefit
calculations on a production volume getting newly acquired outdoor
access of one-eighth (12.5 percent) of year 6 production or 0.225 x
QALL (=.0125 x 1.818 x QALL) to calculate its
benefit value.\21\ This Report finds that the benefit calculation AMS
used in Scenario C is incorrect and overestimates the total value of
benefits.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\21\ The likely transposition error discussed in Section 5.G
affected this calculation. Year 6 production is 710,578,652, or
1.127[supcaret]5 (or 1.818) multiplied by Year 1 production of
390,834,208. One-eighth of year 6 production is 88,822,332. Section
5.G describes how that number was likely incorrectly transcribed to
be 89,361,091.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Alternatively, AMS might have intended to have described Scenario
C.2 rather than Scenario C in its benefits calculation. Scenario C.2
assumes that 50 percent of current production exits the industry in
year 6 and no growth occurs until that time (See Section 4.C). In this
case, the benefits calculated for C.2 would be the same as the benefits
calculated for Scenario B. In that Scenario, 25 percent of year 1
production (0.25 x QALL) gains new outdoor access and this
volume would be multiplied by the WTP to find benefits. Since this also
differs from the 0.225 x QALL value used in the Final and
Withdrawal RIAs, this Report also finds that the calculated benefit for
that Scenario in the Final RIA is inconsistent with the description of
Scenario C.2.
6. Incorrect Use of the Production Levels That Do Not Account for
Increased Mortality When Calculating Benefits
In the Final RIA, AMS stated that it expected layer mortality to
increase from 5 to 8 percent as a result of the OLPP Rule's new outdoor
access requirement, which exposed layers to increased risks of disease
and predation. As a result, AMS developed estimates of after-the-rule
production levels that were 1.4 percent lower than the before-the-rule
levels that specifically reflected this mortality adjustment. While the
cost estimates correctly utilized the relevant after-the-rule
production level, the benefits calculations were calculated based on
the quantity levels that did not take into account the expected
increase in mortality. Details for specific values of the production
before the rule (with the lower mortality rate) and after the rule are
provided in the following section. Because the production level enters
into the benefit calculation multiplicatively, the benefit calculation
is over-estimated by 1.4 percent. This Report finds that AMS erred by
using the before-the-rule production level when the after-the-rule
production level was appropriate.
7. Errors in Cost Calculations in the Final RIA
The cost calculations were not fully documented in the Final RIA
with regard to how the OLPP Rule affected average costs across
operation types. This section describes the cost calculations and notes
several concerns, including how production levels used to calculate
costs and benefits differ, how AMS did not appropriately consider the
costs to aviaries that could not obtain land, and how production shares
were not updated for firm exit. By not appropriately considering the
costs to aviaries that could not obtain land and not updating
production shares for firm exit, AMS likely underestimated the costs to
implementing the rule in specific instances.
The main documentation for the cost and transfer calculations of
the Final RIA was included in workbooks titled ``A-OLPP layer costs--
cage free'' (A-OLPP) and ``Barn and Layer projections FR 01 2017 OMB''
(B-Layer). For the four types of operations (pasture raised, floor
litter, pit litter, and aviary), the A-OLPP file enumerates the costs
of producing organic or cage-free eggs (i.e., feed costs, machinery,
labor, etc.). A-OLPP documents layer numbers, production levels, and
adjustment factors including the death loss rate, which AMS expected to
increase under the OLPP Rule. A-OLPP also reports calculations for
production levels, fixed costs, variable costs, average total costs,
revenue (based on price assumptions), and cost differentials before and
after the OLPP Rule. The cost burden of the rule has two components for
egg producers--increased physical costs and reduced revenue. In the
Final RIA's Tables 16 and 17 on pages 122-123 (which correspond to
Withdrawal Workbook sheets 2 and 3), the ``Cost: Layers'' column refers
to the sum of increased physical costs and reduced revenue.
The A-OLPP file has six sheets. The A-OLPP sheets titled Industry
Cost No Entry (No Entry Sheet) and Industry Cost Entry (Entry Sheet)
calculate total aggregate costs of the rule, including increased
physical costs and reduced revenue for all operation types, under the
alternative assumptions that the industry production did not grow and
that it grew at the 12.7 percent rate. In the Entry and No Entry
Sheets, cell E67 reports total costs, cell E65 reports lost revenue,
and cell E59 reports increased physical costs. These values are the
sums of the values for each operation type, with only the pasture
raised operations incurring no additional increased physical costs or
lost revenue. Cells G36:G38 and D35:D38 show production levels for each
operation type before and after the rule takes effect, the difference
arising from the increase in death loss following the OLPP Rule's
promulgation.\22\ The difference between rates of death loss (reported
in cells B18 and B19) drives the difference in the production levels
before and after the rule takes effect. The A-OLPP file reports total
costs in year 6 of $55,135,426 in the Entry Sheet and $30,325,723 in
the No Entry Sheet. These computations do not consider whether
operations exit in year 6, but are instead based on cells G36:G38, the
production levels after the OLPP Rule takes effect if all operations
are producing.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\22\ Death loss rates before and after are presented in B18 and
B19.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Note that production for each operation in the Entry Sheet is
1.818107555 times greater than its value in the No Entry Sheet. This
indicates that growth does not change the proportions of operation
types in the industry. Also, note that production levels after the rule
takes effect (G39) are 1.4 percent lower than their levels before the
rule takes effect (D39). The higher before-rule production levels form
the baseline production levels in the benefits calculations.
The A-OLPP total cost values in the Entry and No Entry Sheets do
not consider the effect of operation exit. Instead, the B-Layer file
adjusts the total cost values for the shares of year 6 production that
remains in the industry to compute costs under the different Scenarios.
As described in Section 5, AMS expected different proportions of the
producer types to exit the industry in Scenario B and C where exit
occurs.
[[Page 22674]]
Specifically, the 70 percent share of egg production from aviaries
would fall to 25 percent and the 30 percent share of non-aviary
production would fall to 25 percent. Since AMS had different cost
calculations for each type of producer, it should have used these
expected changes in shares to scale costs specifically by operation
type. Instead, it applied a single scaling multiplier to total costs
(across all operation types) based on the aggregate share of year 6
production that remains in the organic egg industry.
In B-Layer, the cell H8 value of $7,541,431 in the ``Transfer--No
Entry'' sheet describes annual layer costs in Scenario C, which
corresponds to Table 16 of the Final RIA.\23\ This value reflects the
$30,325,723 total cost from the Entry Sheet being scaled by \1/4\.\24\
The cell H8 value of $13,784,001 in the ``Transfer to Cage Free'' Sheet
describes annual layer costs in Scenario B, which corresponds to Table
17 of the Final RIA.\25\ This value is \1/4\ of the total cost value of
$55,135,426 recorded in the ``Industry Cost--Entry'' sheet.\26\ The
interpretation of the \1/4\ multiplier is discussed later in this
section.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\23\ The cell I8 value of $170,042,253 is the annual transfers
value reported in sheet 4 of the Withdrawal Workbook.
\24\ In the sheet, the $7,542,431 is the sum of four component
values, but each has the same multiplier and sum to \1/4\ of total
costs in the ``Industry Cost--No Entry'' sheet by construction.
\25\ The cell I8 value of $93,527,000 is the value of annual
transfers value reported in sheet 5 of the Withdrawal Workbook.
\26\ In the sheet, the $13,784,001 is the sum of four component
values, but each has the same multiplier and sum to \1/4\ of total
costs in ``Industry Cost--No Entry'' sheet by construction.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
In B-Layer, the cell H9 value of $3,812,000 in the ``Stay in
Organic'' sheet reflects the one-time fixed costs of aviaries acquiring
land and is equal to Scenario A's year 3 costs in Table 15 of the Final
RIA. Cell H10 of that same sheet calculates recurring annual costs of
$55,135,426 after year 6. As previously discussed in Section 3.C, Table
15 of the Final RIA presents annual cost figures for layers for three
groups of producers divided by the age of the producer.\27\ The values
for the one-and two-year old producer groups correspond to their share
(12 and 24 percent) multiplied by $55,135,426. Section 3.C describes an
error in the Withdrawal RIA whereby the depreciation error was not
entirely removed from the cost calculations for houses older than four
years.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\27\ The distribution of the productive type for this group is
assumed to be the same as it was previously--70 percent aviaries, 10
percent pasture, 10 percent pit litter, and 10 percent floor litter.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The Final RIA's costs calculations for layers of a certain type
(pasture, floor litter, pit litter, and aviaries) reflect two
components--increased physical costs for the portion of production
remaining in the industry and lost revenue for the portion of
production exiting the industry. For each producer type, increased
physical costs equals the number of eggs multiplied by the difference
in the estimated average costs of production before and after the rule.
Lost revenue for layers is the difference in the number of eggs
produced before and after the rule multiplied by the break-even organic
price before the rule. Table 3 provides values of average costs and
break-even price \28\ for each type of operation.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\28\ The break-even price reflects the (before rule) average
costs with an adjustment for the 20 percent of output that goes to
the less-lucrative breaker egg market.
Table 3--Average Costs and Break-Even Prices by Operation Type
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Average costs Break-even egg
Operation type before the Average costs price before
rule after the rule the rule
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Pasture......................................................... $3.0427 $3.043 $3.403
Floor Litter.................................................... 1.8972 1.947 2.121
Pit Litter...................................................... 1.8972 1.947 2.121
Aviary (Can Get Land)........................................... 1.8344 1.891 2.043
Aviary (Can't Get Land)......................................... 1.8344 2.399 2.043
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Note: All values are in dollars per dozen.
Since pasture operations are already fully compliant with the OLPP
Rule, their average costs are equal before and after the rule. A-OLPP
sheet ``Layers-Aviary'' provides average cost and break-even price
calculations for both aviaries that could not obtain land and aviaries
that could. As Table 3 shows, aviaries that could not obtain land faced
a much higher average cost (after the rule) than aviaries that could
obtain land. The ``Aviary (Can't Get Land)'' average cost values
reflect costs if the baseline aviary's post-rule production was one-
third of its pre-rule production, a production level reduction that
mirrors the level of firm exit AMS assumed for the aviaries after the
rule in Scenarios B and C.\29\ Based on comments, AMS increased the
production share of aviaries from 50 percent in the Preliminary RIA to
70 percent in the Final RIA, but assumed that two-thirds of aviaries
would not be able to acquire land. The Final RIA (Passage 17, pages 27-
28) states:
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\29\ In AMS cost calculations in A-OLPP, total cost is the sum
of total fixed costs and total variable costs for a baseline
enterprise budget AMS estimated for a large organic layer operation.
Between firms able to purchase land and firms unable to purchase
land, fixed costs are roughly equal at $420,626 and $418,234,
respectively. On the other hand, total variable costs differ by
approximately an order of three at $4,236,938 and $1,552,299. This
reflects a production level differing by approximately an order of
three at 2,464,000 dozen eggs for farms that can acquire land and
821,333 dozen eggs for farms that cannot acquire land. The average
total cost for farms that can acquire land of $1.8902 per dozen
reflects the sum of fixed and variable costs equaling $4,657,564
divided by 2,464,000 dozen eggs. The average total cost for farms
that cannot acquire land of $2.3992 reflects the sum of fixed and
variable costs $1,970,533 divided by 821,333.
AMS is estimating that about two-thirds of the aviaries,
equivalent to 45 percent of organic egg production, and that a
portion of non-aviary production, which accounts for 5 percent of
organic egg production, will not be able to acquire additional land
and will move to the cage-free market. In summary, AMS believes that
50 percent of organic production may transition to cage-free egg
production, while the remainder would be incentivized to remain in
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
the organic market and obtain needed land.
Despite calculating this figure within internal spreadsheets, AMS did
not apply or publish the ``aviary (can't get land)'' average cost
values in the Final RIA. In the Final RIA, AMS (Passage 18, page 24)
writes:
AMS acknowledges that some producers may opt to remain in
organic production by obtaining non-adjacent land and constructing
new facilities. While AMS is not estimating aggregate costs based on
assumptions about what proportion of organic producers may decide to
remain in organic production by constructing new facilities, we are
providing some parameters of such costs. Based on information from
the
[[Page 22675]]
organic egg producers, AMS estimates that the costs of aviary
housing is [sic] $70/hen. Further, we believe that larger organic
operations have a minimum of 100,000 hens; medium scale have between
30,000-100,000 birds and smaller scale less than 30,000 birds.
Therefore, the corresponding estimates for housing costs for
producers of each size category: $7 million minimum (large scale);
$2.1-$7 million (medium); $2.1 million maximum (smaller scale). In
addition, producers that construct new aviary facilities to house
100,000 birds would need approximately 6.12 acres of land for
housing and outdoor space. This amounts to nearly $28,000 in land
costs.
Since AMS deviated from those provisions, we are not utilizing
the associated cost projections. [italics added]
In the first italicized passage, AMS states that some aviary operations
that could not acquire additional (adjacent) land might be forced to
buy land elsewhere and build new facilities to remain in operation. AMS
then outlines ``parameters of such [building] costs'' before stating in
the second italicized passage that it would not utilize these costs.
Table 4 lists the production levels before and after the OLPP Rule
for each type of operation for Scenario A. The total level of eggs
before accounting for the rule's impact on mortality--710,578,627
dozen--corresponds to the level of eggs in year 6 as listed on Table 6
of the Withdrawal Workbook. The numbers of eggs before and after the
rule differ because AMS expected layer mortality to increase with
outdoor access. As we note in Section 6, AMS used the higher before-
the-rule production level rather than the lower after-the-rule
production levels in the benefits calculations and this led to their
over-estimation.
Table 4--Production Values, Cost Increases, and Lost Revenues From Entry Sheet
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Type Eggs after rule Eggs before rule Increased costs Lost revenue
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Pasture................................. 64,495,917 64,495,917 $0 $0
Fl. Litter.............................. 70,682,553 71,786,968 3,506,265 2,343,009
Pit Litter.............................. 70,682,553 71,786,968 3,507,153 2,343,009
Aviary.................................. 494,777,870 502,508,774 27,641,969 15,794,020
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
Total............................... 700,638,893 710,578,627 34,655,387 20,480,038
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Increased costs and lost revenues equal $55,134,539. As we note in
Section 3.C, this value would have been the total cost to egg producers
in Scenario A if the depreciation treatment had not been applied for 4-
year-old houses. This value is the sum of total increased costs--
$34,655,387--and total lost revenue--$20,480,038. Importantly, the
computation for increased costs for aviaries uses only the average
costs for aviaries that can obtain land. Because AMS estimated that
about 45 percent of production was comprised of aviaries that could not
obtain land and because these aviaries have far higher costs than
aviaries that can obtain land, using only the average cost for aviaries
that can obtain land for all aviaries will lead AMS estimate of costs
for Scenario A to be underestimated.
Under Scenario B, the organic egg industry grows at a 12.7 percent
rate between year 1 and year 6, after which time half of the market
participants leave the industry. To obtain the increased costs
estimate, AMS used \1/4\ of the year 6 production levels for each type
of operation and then multiplied these values by the difference in
average costs before and after the OLPP Rule, as with Scenario A.
Similarly, for decreased revenues, AMS used production values before
and after the rule that were \1/4\ of the values used in Scenario A.
This Report notes that production levels enter linearly into the
formulas for increased costs and lost revenue. As a result, the total
costs reported in Table 17 for layers are $13,784,000.
In Scenario C, the industry grows at the 12.7 percent rate with no
entry from non-compliant producers and then, in year 6, 50 percent of
producers exit and transition to cage-free production. Table 5 below
shows the level of eggs produced before and after the OLPP Rule with no
growth. Based on these levels, Table 5 shows that total increased costs
are $19,061,241 and lost revenue is $11,264,482 so that total costs are
$30,325,723. As with Scenario B, the numbers of eggs used in the
calculations (both before and after the rule) are multiplied by \1/4\
and the estimated value calculated for Scenario B is \1/4\ of
$30,325,723 (the sum of increased costs and lost revenue) in Table 5
below, or $7,541,431.
Table 5--Production, Increased Costs, and Lost Revenues From A-OLPP No Entry Sheet
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Type Eggs after rule Eggs before rule Increased costs Lost revenue
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Pasture................................. 35,474,203 35,474,203 $0 $0
Fl. Litter.............................. 38,876,992 39,484,445 1,928,524 1,288,707
Pit Litter.............................. 38,876,992 39,484,445 1,929,013 1,288,707
Aviary.................................. 272,138,944 276,391,115 15,203,704 8,687,067
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
Total............................... 385,367,131 390,834,208 19,061,241 11,264,482
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Based on these figures, this Report finds three errors with the cost
calculations in the Final RIA, as described in the following sections.
A. Production Levels Used To Calculate Costs and Benefits Differ
The Final RIA (Passage 19, page 27) indicates that:
AMS assumes that operations representing 75 percent of organic
egg production could incur costs for purchasing and maintaining
additional land to comply with the outdoor stocking density
requirement.
Seventy five percent of the year 6 production (711 million dozen eggs)
is 532 million dozen eggs. In its calculation of benefits, AMS sought
to include only benefits from production
[[Page 22676]]
of organic eggs that gained new outdoor access as defined under the
OLPP Rule and used 50 percent of year 6 production, or 355,289,326
dozen eggs, to reflect that production. The share of houses that were
projected to gain new outdoor access under this scenario is higher than
50 percent because, at a minimum, all aviary production remaining in
the industry would gain outdoor access and aviaries comprise 70 percent
of production. For this reason, this Report finds that the assumed 50
percent share of production that gains new outdoor access is
inconsistent with the page 27 text.\30\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\30\ Despite the page 27 statement that 75 percent of production
would need to purchase additional land, the Entry and No Entry
Sheets describe three producer types (pit-litter, floor-litter, and
aviary) that comprise 90 percent of production and would incur
increased costs as a result of the OLPP Rule. A close reading of the
cost figures in A-OLPP indicates that little or no cost for added
land for pit-litter and floor-litter producers was included in the
cost calculations. It is unclear whether AMS considered production
that gained outdoor access under the rule as production by
operations paying additional costs under the rule or firms needing
to acquire land under the rule. If it is firms needing to acquire
land, the 75 percent figure may be accurate.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
In Scenario B, AMS computes costs based on \1/4\ of total costs in
the Entry Sheet (relating to year 1 production levels). In the benefits
section, AMS computes benefits based on \1/8\ (of year 6) production
(after correcting for the error described in Section 3.C). In this
case, AMS assumed that only 50 percent of production would gain new
outdoor access as a result of the OLPP Rule and thereby create new
consumer benefits. However, this Report finds the 50 percent share to
be inconsistent with the page 27 text indicated that 75 percent of
production would need to acquire land to gain new outdoor access and
its costs calculations that approximately 90 percent of production
volume pays a higher cost.
For Scenario C, AMS computes costs based on \1/4\ of total costs
reported in the No Entry Sheet (relating to year 1 production levels)
but computes benefits based on \1/8\ of year 1 production. Following
the same logic as with Scenarios A and B, this Report finds the 50
percent share to be inconsistent with the page 27 text.
B. AMS Did Not Appropriately Consider the Costs to Aviaries That Could
Not Obtain Land
Aviaries comprised 70 percent of organic egg production and AMS
estimated that approximately two-thirds of aviary producers would be
unable to acquire the land required under the OLPP Rule. Scenario A
calculates costs under the assumption that all current firms continue
to operate under the new rule conditions, regardless of their ability
to acquire additional land. Whether aviaries would become compliant by
acquiring non-adjacent land and building new facilities (as suggested
in Passage 17) or reducing production volumes is unclear. Despite
acknowledging that the aviaries that comprised 45 percent of production
that could not acquire land would face far higher average costs than
the aviaries comprising 25 percent of production that could acquire
land, AMS applied the lower average cost to all aviaries. This Report
further notes that because AMS did not present any of these key
underlying cost calculations in the Final RIA, outside reviewers may
not have been aware of the modeling specification. Despite stating in
Passage 18 that a cost estimate for aviaries that could not acquire
land would not be used, this Report finds that AMS still did not fully
explain why the lower cost estimate was used and concludes that costs
for Scenario A were underestimated as a result.
C. Production Shares Not Updated for Firm Exit
In Scenarios B and C, AMS assumed that, following industry growth
for five years, 50 percent of firms exit the industry as a result of
the rule. In Passage 17, AMS indicated that \2/3\ of aviaries would
exit the industry after the OLPP Rule took effect. This implies that
the ratio of aviaries to non-aviaries (pasture, floor litter, and pit
litter) falls considerably after the rule. In Scenario B, however, AMS
used cost calculations that assume the shares of operation types are
unchanged. This is significant for two reasons. First, a larger share
of remaining firms may be comprised of pastured raised operations.
Within the context of the AMS analysis, an increased share of pasture
raised operations causes both costs and benefits to fall. This occurs
because operations that are already compliant with the rule do not
produce any new benefit after the rule takes effect and do not incur
any costs to become compliant.
Second, a change in the composition of operations after the rule
takes effect is likely to cause the average price of eggs to increase
to reflect its new higher break-even level across all producers.
Following the rule, firms will exit the industry if the average price
of eggs is less than the break-even price. Price, however, will rise as
firms leave the industry. Eventually, the average price reaches the
break-even price level and firms no longer exit the market. If the
proportion of firm types is unchanged, the increase in the break-even
will be close to the average cost of implementing the rule. Table 3
indicates that the maximum change in average costs across all
operations is relatively small at 6 cents. Pasture raised operations,
however, have far higher average costs (and related break-even costs)
before the rule than other operation types. By assuming that the share
of producer types is unchanged after the rule, AMS constrained the
rule's effect on the break-even price to be the cost of compliance
(i.e., the change in average costs) within an operation type and
precluded a separate industry composition effect due to the industry
shift from aviaries to non-aviaries. This industry composition effect
will increase production costs on average for the industry independent
of the increased cost of compliance.
Non-Material Errors in the Final and Withdrawal RIAs
1. Other Transposition Errors
a. Costs in Withdrawal RIA--In the Withdrawal RIA's Table C, the
cost savings are erroneously stated as ``$28.7 to $29.9'' under the
assumed conditions of: ``All producers remain in organic market;
Organic layer and broiler populations continue growth rates after
rule.'' The correct values are reported in Table A as: ``$28.7 to
$31.0.''
b. Year 4 Egg Production--The Withdrawal Workbook Sheets 6, 7, 8,
and 9 list 599,453,903 eggs being produced in year 4. Based on the
stated 12.7% growth rate this value should have been 559,453,904. The
italicized material suggests that a transposition error likely
occurred.
2. Weighting of WTP Values
This Report notes that Passage 1 refers to the WTP of ``the
majority of the consumers'' while Passage 2 refers to the ``mean
premium'' for each of the two subsets of additional consumers' WTP.
This Report assesses the mean premium as the more appropriate value to
apply for rulemaking purposes. This rationale is not cited in the
Withdrawal RIA but supports AMS's decision to correct the Final RIA
numbers.
This Report also notes that Table 8 provides WTP estimates
(identical to the ``mean premium'' cited in Passage 2) for two other
subsets of all consumers--consumers differing by their perception of
quality of an animal-friendly product and consumers differing by their
perception of management practices on hen welfare. In the Final RIA and
Withdrawal RIA, the high-end and low-end values for the WTP are then
used to create separate high-end and low-end
[[Page 22677]]
estimates of the benefits under the rule. Also, despite the
availability of the other subsets, only the ``receiving of additional
information'' subset is used for the high and low values. Later those
two estimates are averaged in the computation of the net benefits of
the rule without regard for any weighing of what proportions of
consumers actually belong to those subsets.
From a methodological standpoint, this Report notes that the use of
the estimate of the ``receiving of additional information'' subset,
rather than the other subsets, is inappropriate. The ``receiving of
additional information'' is a treatment variable where subjects receive
additional information (relative to the control treatment of no
additional information) on the environmental consequences of their
choices. The other two subsets--consumers organized by perception of
quality and consumers organized by perception of management--represent
true control variables because they reflect consumer perceptions formed
outside of the choice experiment, as opposed to information provided by
the experimental designers. A more appropriate method of developing and
compiling the WTP from the two subsets would have been to use values of
the WTP from one of the two control groups and weight their effect on
the final benefit values by the share of consumers in each group. In
the case of the information provided, there is no reason to assume that
the proportion of the consumers to which the authors provided this
information is equal to the share of actual consumers purchasing eggs
who might have that information.
Despite the methodological concerns in the choice of subsets and
the weighting of the subset groups, benefit calculations are unlikely
to change materially when either change is applied. Because the
``received additional information'' and ``did not receive additional
information'' treatment groups had nearly equal numbers of consumers--
499 and 475--the weighted and unweighted averages--20.5 cents and 20.2
cents--are very similar. Moreover, the weighted averages of the other
two subsets--20.9 cents for ``perceptions of quality'' and 20.3 cents
for ``perception of management practices''--are very similar to the
``received additional information'' subset.
This Report concurs with the assessment of the Withdrawal RIA that
the Final RIA used inappropriate values for the WTP in its calculation
of the benefits. The Report cites two methodological concerns in the
Withdrawal RIA's correction of this error. However, this Report also
notes that using benefits values with a more appropriate specification
in the benefits calculation would not change the findings
substantially.
3. Different Depreciation Periods Are Used in Different Sections of the
Analysis
In the proposed OLPP Rule published April 13, 2016 (81 FR 21956),
AMS states that it applied a depreciation period for hen layer houses
of either 12.5 or 13 years, the difference presumably reflecting the
need for a round number. AMS applied the depreciation rate in three
ways. First, a 12.5-year depreciation period is used to set the
compliance phase period. Specifically, in the proposed OLPP Rule, AMS
states that the difference between the depreciation rate (12.5 years)
and average age of organic aviary layer houses (7.6 years) is roughly 5
years. Therefore, a 5-year implementation period would allow organic
egg producers, on average, to recover the costs of a poultry house. 71
FR 21986.
Second, a 13-year period is used in the depreciation treatment of
costs and benefits in the proposed OLPP Rule. Despite the errors
already mentioned in this section, the depreciation treatment was
intended to be removed from calculations in the Final RIA. Third, AMS
followed the standard accounting practice of converting the single
period cost of a durable asset to a recurring annual cost using the
depreciation concept. In this method, AMS divided an asset's costs by
its depreciable life to create an equivalent annual cost in using the
asset. In using a longer depreciation period of 20 rather than 13
years, AMS decreased the annual costs of using the asset by
approximately 35 percent (7/20).\31\ However, since this asset
depreciation cost (the term being used in the ordinary accounting
sense) is a relatively small portion of annual costs, this Report
assesses this discrepancy as being non-material.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\31\ If a 20-year depreciation period is used, then annual costs
are 5 percent of the asset's cost. If a 13-year depreciation period
is used, then annual costs are 7.69 percent of the asset's cost.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Appendix A--Cross Referencing of Withdrawal Workbook Page Numbers and
Final RIA Tables
Withdrawal Workbook Sheet 1 corresponds to Final RIA,
Table 15 titled ``Estimated costs for organic egg and poultry
sector--full compliance.''
Withdrawal Workbook Sheet 2 corresponds to Final RIA,
Table 16 titled ``Estimated cost for organic egg and poultry
production--some operations move to cage free in year 6 (2022).''
Withdrawal Workbook Sheet 3 corresponds to Final RIA,
Table 17 titled ``Estimated cost for organic egg and poultry
production--some operations move to cage free in year 6 (2022); new
entry continues after rule.''
Withdrawal Workbook Sheet 4 corresponds to Final RIA,
Table 18 titled ``Estimated transfers (foregone profit) for organic
egg and poultry production--some operations move to cage free in
year 6 (2022).''
Withdrawal Workbook Sheet 5 corresponds to Final RIA,
Table 19 titled ``Estimated cost for organic egg and poultry
production--some operations move to cage free in year 6 (2022); new
entry continues after rule.''
Withdrawal Workbook Sheet 6 includes intermediate
calculations to support the benefit figures associated with Scenario
A.
Withdrawal Workbook Sheet 7 includes intermediate
calculations to support the benefit figures associated with Scenario
B.
Withdrawal Workbook Sheet 8 includes intermediate
calculations to support the benefit figures associated with Scenario
C.
Withdrawal Workbook Sheet 9 corresponds to Figure 6 of
the Final RIA.
Withdrawal Workbook Sheet 10 includes calculations
based on data from the National Animal Health Monitoring Survey that
describes the age distribution of layer houses.
Bruce Summers,
Administrator, Agricultural Marketing Service.
[FR Doc. 2020-08548 Filed 4-22-20; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE P