2018 Quadrennial Regulatory Review-Review of the Commission's Broadcast Ownership Rules, 6741-6757 [2019-03278]
Download as PDF
Federal Register / Vol. 84, No. 40 / Thursday, February 28, 2019 / Proposed Rules
burden on providers and suppliers to
the maximum possible extent. At this
time, we believe we can best achieve
this balance by issuing this continuation
document.
Therefore, this document extends the
timeline for publication of the final rule
for 1 year, until March 1, 2020.
Dated: February 25, 2019.
Ann C. Agnew,
Executive Secretary to the Department,
Department of Health and Human Services.
[FR Doc. 2019–03697 Filed 2–27–19; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 4120–01–P
FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS
COMMISSION
47 CFR Part 73
[MB Docket No. 18–349; FCC 18–179]
2018 Quadrennial Regulatory Review—
Review of the Commission’s
Broadcast Ownership Rules
Federal Communications
Commission.
ACTION: Proposed rule.
AGENCY:
In this document, the
Commission’s Notice of Proposed
Rulemaking (NPRM) initiates the 2018
quadrennial review of its media
ownership rules, launched pursuant to
a requirement of the
Telecommunications Act of 1996 (1996
Act) that the Commission review its
media ownership rules every four years
to determine whether they remain
‘‘necessary in the public interest as the
result of competition’’ and to ‘‘repeal or
modify any determine[d] to be no longer
in the public interest.’’ The three rules
currently subject to review are the Local
Radio Ownership Rule, the Local
Television Ownership Rule, and the
Dual Network Rule. The NPRM seeks
comment on whether, given the current
state of the media marketplace, the
Commission should retain, modify, or
eliminate any of these rules. The NPRM
also seeks comment on several
proposals offered as potential prodiversity initiatives.
DATES: Comments due April 29, 2019.
Reply comments due May 29, 2019.
ADDRESSES: Interested parties may
submit comments and replies, identified
by MB Docket No. 18–349, by any of the
following methods:
• Federal eRulemaking Portal: https://
www.regulations.gov. Follow the
instructions for submitting comments.
• Federal Communications
Commission’s website: https://
www.fcc.gov/cgb/ecfs/. Follow the
instructions for submitting comments.
khammond on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with PROPOSALS
SUMMARY:
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:17 Feb 27, 2019
Jkt 247001
• Mail: Filings can be sent by hand or
messenger delivery, by commercial
overnight courier, or by first-class or
overnight U.S. Postal Service mail
(although the Commission continues to
experience delays in receiving U.S.
Postal Service mail). All filings must be
addressed to the Commission’s
Secretary, Office of the Secretary,
Federal Communications Commission.
For more detailed filing instructions,
see the Procedural Matters section
below.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
Brendan Holland, Industry Analysis
Division, Media Bureau,
Brendan.Holland@fcc.gov (202) 418–
2757.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: This is a
summary of the Commission’s Notice of
Proposed Rulemaking (NPRM) in MB
Docket No. 18–349; FCC 18–179,
adopted on December 12, 2018, and
released on December 13, 2018. The full
text of this document is available for
public inspection during regular
business hours in the FCC Reference
Center, 445 12th Street SW, Room CY–
A257, Washington, DC 20554, or online
at https://docs.fcc.gov/public/
attachments/FCC-18-179A1.pdf. To
request this document in accessible
formats for people with disabilities (e.g.,
braille, large print, electronic files,
audio format, etc.) or to request
reasonable accommodations (e.g.,
accessible format documents, sign
language interpreters, CART, etc.), send
an email to fcc504@fcc.gov or call the
FCC’s Consumer and Governmental
Affairs Bureau at (202) 418–0530
(voice), (202) 418–0432 (TTY).
Synopsis
1. Background. Last year, the
Commission completed its prior
combined 2010/2014 review of its
media ownership rules by adopting an
Order on Reconsideration (2010/2014
Quadrennial Review Order on
Reconsideration) of its initial Order
(2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Order),
a reconsideration that relaxed or
eliminated several rules, including
repeal of the previous bans on
newspaper/broadcast and radio/
television cross-ownership in a market.
In the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review
Order on Reconsideration the
Commission revised the Local
Television Ownership Rule by
eliminating the requirement that, in
order to own two stations in a market,
eight independent voices must remain
in the market post-transaction, and
concluded that it would consider, on a
case-by-case basis, combinations that
would otherwise be barred by the
PO 00000
Frm 00037
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
6741
prohibition on ownership of two topfour ranked stations in a market. In
eliminating and revising its rules, the
Commission recognized the dynamic
changes in the media marketplace and
the wealth of information sources now
available to consumers. The
Commission also found that, while the
record in the 2010/2014 Quadrennial
Review supported adoption of an
incubator program to foster the entry of
new and diverse voices in the
broadcasting industry, the structure and
implementation of such a program
required further exploration.
Accordingly, the Commission sought
comment on these issues, and on
August 2, 2018, adopted a Report and
Order (Incubator Order) establishing an
incubator program to foster new entry
into the broadcasting industry. Under
the program, an established broadcaster
(i.e., incubating entity) will provide a
new entrant or small broadcaster (i.e.,
incubated entity) with training,
financing, and access to resources that
would be otherwise inaccessible to
these entities. In return for this support,
the incubating entity can receive a
waiver of the applicable Local Radio
Ownership Rule that it can use either in
the incubated market or in a comparable
market within three years of the
successful conclusion of a qualifying
incubation relationship.
2. Multiple parties sought
reconsideration and judicial review of
the Commission’s 2010/2014
Quadrennial Review Order, 2010/2014
Quadrennial Review Order on
Reconsideration and Incubator Order.
The Third Circuit U.S. Court of Appeals
has consolidated the petitions for
judicial review of these Orders and its
review is pending.
3. Local Radio Ownership Rule. The
rule allows an entity to own: (1) Up to
eight commercial radio stations in radio
markets with at least 45 radio stations,
no more than five of which may be in
the same service (AM or FM); (2) up to
seven commercial radio stations in radio
markets with 30–44 radio stations, no
more than four of which may be in the
same service (AM or FM); (3) up to six
commercial radio stations in radio
markets with 15–29 radio stations, no
more than four of which may be in the
same service (AM or FM); and (4) up to
five commercial radio stations in radio
markets with 14 or fewer radio stations,
no more than three of which may be in
the same service (AM or FM), provided
that the entity does not own more than
50 percent of the radio stations in the
market unless the combination
comprises not more than one AM and
one FM station. When determining the
total number of radio stations within a
E:\FR\FM\28FEP1.SGM
28FEP1
khammond on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with PROPOSALS
6742
Federal Register / Vol. 84, No. 40 / Thursday, February 28, 2019 / Proposed Rules
market, only full-power commercial and
noncommercial radio stations are
counted for purposes of the rule. Radio
markets are defined by Nielsen Audio
where applicable and, in Puerto Rico,
the contour-overlap methodology used
in areas outside of defined and rated
Nielsen Audio Metro markets.
4. In the 2010/2014 Quadrennial
Review Order, the Commission
concluded that local radio ownership
limits promoted competition, a public
interest benefit providing a sufficient
basis for retaining a local radio
ownership rule. The Commission
affirmed its previous finding that
competitive local radio markets help
promote viewpoint diversity and
localism and are consistent with the
Commission’s goal of promoting
minority and female broadcast station
ownership. In the subsequent 2010/2014
Quadrennial Review Order on
Reconsideration, the Commission
adopted a presumption, to be further
considered in this 2018 Quadrennial
Review, in favor of waiving the Local
Radio Ownership Rule for qualifying
radio stations within embedded markets
(i.e., smaller markets, as defined by
Nielsen Audio, that are contained
within the boundaries of a larger, parent
Nielsen Audio Metro market) where the
parent market currently has multiple
embedded markets (i.e., New York and
Washington, DC). Such a waiver would
permit the applicant to comply with
ownership limits determined by
examining only the embedded market,
and not both the embedded and parent
markets. Stations would qualify for
waivers under two conditions: (1)
Compliance with the numerical
ownership limits using the Nielsen
Audio Metro methodology in each
embedded market, and (2) compliance
with the ownership limits using the
contour-overlap methodology applicable
to undefined markets in lieu of the
Commission’s current parent market
analysis.
5. The Commission seeks comment
generally on all aspects of the Local
Radio Ownership Rule, including
whether the rule remains necessary in
the public interest to promote
competition and specifically, whether
there have been any changes in the
marketplace since the 2010/2014
Quadrennial Review that would affect
this determination. The Commission
also seeks comment on whether, in
today’s radio marketplace, the rule
remains necessary to promote other
Commission policy goals such as
viewpoint diversity, localism, and
female and minority broadcast
ownership. Commenters are asked to
explain in detail and support with
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:17 Feb 27, 2019
Jkt 247001
evidence their reasons for any
recommended rule changes. If the rule
is retained, the Commission will
analyze relevant parts of the rule to
examine whether each part remains
necessary in the public interest due to
competition or whether it should be
modified or eliminated. Thus, the
Commission seeks comment on each of
the specific aspects of the rule’s
operation, including the relevant
product market, market size tiers,
numerical limits, and AM/FM subcaps,
to assess whether these subparts remain
necessary or whether any of all of them
should be modified or eliminated. If the
rule is retained but modified, the
Commission seeks comment on whether
and how the rule changes should apply
to any pending applications. The
Commission also seeks comment on
whether to make permanent the interim
contour-overlap methodology used to
determine ownership limits in areas
outside the boundaries of defined
Nielsen Audio Metro markets, and on
the issue of embedded market
transactions.
6. In anticipation of further
consideration of the presumption in
favor of waiving the Local Radio
Ownership Rule for radio stations
within embedded markets, the National
Association of Broadcasters (NAB)
submitted a proposal to, among other
things, allow an entity in the top 75
Nielsen Audio Metro markets to own or
control up to eight commercial FM
stations and unlimited AM stations in
any of those markets. NAB also
proposed that entities in those markets
should be permitted to own up to two
additional FM stations if they
participated in the Commission’s
incubator program. NAB also proposed
eliminating all limits on FM and AM
ownership in all other markets. NAB
claimed that these rule relaxations
remove constraints on radio
broadcasters’ ability to compete on a
level playing field in today’s digital
audio world where, NAB claimed the
Commission cannot ignore, broadcast
radio dominance has declined relative
to streaming services such as Pandora
and Spotify, satellite radio, podcasts,
Facebook and You Tube, described as
‘‘multiple major sources of competition
for both listeners and advertisers in the
audio marketplace.’’ Thus, according to
NAB, the more relevant factor for
listeners has become where services can
be accessed, which is now the same for
radio and other services, rather than
where services are headquartered. NAB
added that allowing radio owners to
achieve economies of scale and scope
would enable them to improve their
PO 00000
Frm 00038
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
informational and entertainment
programming. Other radio broadcasters
similarly claimed that digital
competitors such as Google and
Facebook enjoy perceived advantages in
ability to target advertising, do not need
to employ local advertising salesforces,
and had therefore captured significant
shares of the local advertising market to
the detriment of local broadcast radio.
Other parties argued in opposition to
NAB’s proposal that allowing radio
broadcasters to buy more stations would
not help them compete against internet
services such as Google and Facebook,
the size of station portfolios had little
relevance to dollars allocated to free
radio, advertisers did not view radio
and internet services as comparable, and
radio remains the preferred audio
medium for entertainment and local
news.
7. The Commission received many
additional comments in response to a
request for updated information on the
status of competition in the marketplace
for the delivery of audio programming
in seeking to prepare a biennial
marketplace report for Congress,
comments which are incorporated into
the record of this 2018 Quadrennial
Review. NAB provided information and
statistical data purporting to show how
fragmented the listening market has
become, and a coalition of radio
broadcasters claimed that radio listening
has shrunk as audiences divide their
time among other audio providers not
subject to the same regulatory burdens
as radio broadcasters. Other radio
station owners asserted that the
Commission’s ownership limits prevent
them from achieving the economies of
scale and scope they need to compete
with satellite radio and online audio
services. On the other hand, coalitions
representing musicians, recording
artists, and representatives of the music
industry argued that AM/FM radio
continues to dominate the audio
marketplace and that experience shows
that consolidation in the radio industry
harms small broadcasters and leads to
the homogenization of programming.
8. Market Definition. The Commission
concluded in the 2010/2014
Quadrennial Review Order that the
broadcast radio listening market
remains the relevant product market for
purposes of the Local Radio Ownership
Rule and declined to expand its
definition of the market to include nonbroadcast audio sources, such as
satellite radio and online audio services.
The Commission’s based this
conclusion on the fact that broadcast
radio stations provide ‘‘free, over-the-air
programming tailored to the needs of
the stations’ local markets,’’ while in
E:\FR\FM\28FEP1.SGM
28FEP1
khammond on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with PROPOSALS
Federal Register / Vol. 84, No. 40 / Thursday, February 28, 2019 / Proposed Rules
contrast, satellite radio is a subscription
service, online audio requires an
internet connection, and neither
typically provides programming
responsive to local needs and interests.
Similarly, in evaluating a broadcast
radio merger of Entercom
Communications and CBS in November
2017, the Department of Justice (DOJ)
also considered the radio market,
concluding that ‘‘[m]any local and
national advertisers consider Englishlanguage broadcast radio to be a
particularly effective or important
means to reach their desired customers,
and do not consider advertisements on
other media, including non-Englishlanguage broadcast radio, digital music
streaming services (such as Pandora),
and television, to be reasonable
substitutes.’’
9. The Commission now seeks
comment on these differing perspectives
of the state of the audio marketplace and
on whether and how these perspectives
should affect its understanding of the
market for purposes of the Local Radio
Ownership Rule. Should the
Commission take DOJ’s finding on the
radio market into account and if so,
how? Should the Commission continue
to consider only local broadcast radio
stations for purposes of the Local Radio
Ownership Rule or should it revise its
market definition to include other audio
sources? Do local radio stations face
direct competition today from satellite
radio and online audio services? To
what extent has radio’s ability to attract
listeners and advertisers been affected
by satellite radio and online audio? Do
advertisers view satellite radio and
audio streaming services as substitutes
for advertising on broadcast radio? How
should the impact of internet services
like Google and Facebook on local
advertising markets factor into our
consideration of the Local Radio
Ownership Rule? Do consumers view
non-broadcast audio services as
meaningful substitutes for local radio
stations? Do non-broadcast audio
services provide programming that
responds to the needs and interests of
local markets? Does radio’s free, overthe-air availability make it unique or
non-substitutable in the audio
marketplace? To what extent, if any,
should the Commission consider the
deployment of In Band on Channel
digital radio technology and its role in
enabling station owners to expand their
program offerings and increase their
economies of scale and scope? If the
Commission were to revise its market
definition, what non-broadcast sources
should it include, and how should it
count them or otherwise factor them
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:17 Feb 27, 2019
Jkt 247001
into its rule for purposes of determining
market size tiers and numerical limits?
Could or should the Commission
subtract from any consideration of nonbroadcast sources the amount of online
audio that listeners in a local market
stream from over-the-air radio
broadcasts? How would an expanded
definition better serve Commission
policy goals, if at all?
10. Market Size Tiers. In the 2010/
2014 Quadrennial Review Order, the
Commission retained the Local Radio
Ownership Rule’s longstanding
approach of imposing numerical
ownership limits based on market size
tiers and determining market size by
counting the number of commercial and
noncommercial radio stations within
the market. The Commission declined to
change the rule to treat embedded
markets as separate markets. In
addition, the Commission kept in place
the demarcations of the four tiers set by
Congress in 1996, which draw the lines
among Nielsen Audio Metro markets at
45 plus, 30–44, 15–29, and 14 or fewer
radio stations, including noncommercial
stations. The Commission seeks
comment on whether it should retain
this approach of using market size tiers,
and if it does so, whether the current
demarcations should remain. Is there
any reason to discontinue including
noncommercial radio stations in market
counts? How well has the rule’s tiered
structure served the rule’s purposes, and
does it promote the policy goals of
competition, localism, and viewpoint
diversity in today’s radio marketplace?
NAB’s proposal would divide radio
markets into only two tiers—the top 75
Nielsen Audio Metro markets and all
other markets (i.e., Nielsen Audio Metro
markets outside of the top 75 and all
undefined markets). What would be the
advantages and disadvantages of
creating a different number of tiers,
including moving from a four-tiered to
a two-tiered approach? If the
Commission were to collapse four tiers
into two, should it draw the line where
NAB proposes? Commenters are invited
to offer alternative proposals for a tiered
approach or for a different type of
approach altogether. For example, if the
Commission changed from tiers based
on station counts, should it consider
tiers based on advertising revenue, or
some other factor, rather than using
Nielsen’s Audio Metro market rankings
as NAB proposes, which are based on
population? Would advertising revenue
provide a sufficiently stable
measurement and how would such a
measurement fit with defining the
relevant product market as the broadcast
radio listening market? How would the
PO 00000
Frm 00039
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
6743
Commission and potential applicants
obtain reliable advertising revenue data
for all radio stations? Should the
Commission factor non-broadcast audio
sources in any tiered approach, and if
so, how should it do so? For example:
(1) If the Commission modifies its
current tiers or creates new tiers, should
it account for variations across markets
in broadband access and adoption rates;
(2) should the Commission treat fixed
and mobile or wired and wireless
broadband the same; and (3) how
granularly can and should the
Commission measure listening rates for
satellite radio and online audio
services?
11. In addition, should any
modifications to the current tiered
approach affect how the Commission
applies the rule to areas outside the
boundaries of defined Nielsen Audio
Metro markets, and if so, how? NAB
proposes removing all radio ownership
limits for undefined areas. Would
NAB’s proposal be consistent with
Commission policy goals or would it
lead to excessive consolidation in those
outside areas, and what alternative
approach could the Commission take in
areas of the country that are undefined
by Nielsen Audio? Further, the contouroverlap methodology has been
successfully applied on an interim basis
to undefined markets for years and the
Commission previously rejected
arguments that it permitted too much
consolidation in certain markets. Is this
approach the most effective and
practical for determining ownership
limits in areas outside defined Nielsen
Audio Metro markets and should the
Commission therefore make it
permanent? Any commenters opposed
to adopting the contour-overlap
methodology on a permanent basis
should explain their reasoning and
propose a detailed alternative supported
by evidence.
12. Numerical Limits. In the 2010/
2014 Quadrennial Review Order, the
Commission declined to relax or tighten
the numerical limits restricting the
number of radio stations an entity may
own within a radio market. The
Commission seeks comment on whether
it is necessary as a result of competition
to maintain the numerical limits for any
or all of the market size tiers. If the
Commission retains existing market
tiers, are existing limits restricting the
number of radio stations an entity may
own within a radio market set
appropriately for each of the market size
tiers? Do the current limits adequately
prevent a radio broadcaster from
amassing excessive local market power?
Conversely, do they permit sufficient
growth to enable radio broadcasters to
E:\FR\FM\28FEP1.SGM
28FEP1
khammond on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with PROPOSALS
6744
Federal Register / Vol. 84, No. 40 / Thursday, February 28, 2019 / Proposed Rules
obtain the additional assets they may
need to improve the quality of their
service? Commenters should provide
concrete, actual examples of markets
where the current limits are either too
restrictive or too lenient, explain how
those examples typify other markets in
that tier, and specify the benefits to
those markets that would be gained by
revising the limits.
13. The Commission also seeks
comment on whether it should account
for the different signal strengths of radio
stations by weighing different classes of
radio stations differently for purposes of
applying the numerical limits. For
example, the Commission could
consider a Class A AM station to be
worth two stations, whereas a Class D
AM station could be counted as one half
a station. What would be the costs and
benefits of such an approach? What
values should be accorded to the
different classes of radio stations if the
Commission adopts such an approach?
The Commission previously considered
a proposal to assign different values to
radio stations of different classes for
purposes of determining market size
tiers and seeks comment on assigning
varying weights to different classes of
radio stations when applying the
numerical limits.
14. In addition, the Commission seeks
comment on NAB’s proposal to
maintain the eight-station limit for the
top 75 Nielsen Audio Metro markets but
to apply it only to FM stations, thereby
allowing unlimited AM ownership.
NAB further proposes allowing an
owner in the top 75 Nielson Audio
Metro markets to acquire up to two
additional FM stations if it participates
in (and, the Commission assumes,
successfully completes) the incubator
program. For all other markets, NAB
urges the elimination of numerical
limits for both FM and AM services. The
Commission seeks comment on all
aspects of NAB’s proposed changes to
the numerical limits and invites
alternative proposals. What would be
the likely effects of removing FM limits
in most markets? What would be the
likely effects of allowing unlimited AM
ownership across all markets? Would
such actions, on balance, promote
competition by enabling owners to
increase their assets, or would they
harm competition and/or ownership
diversity by driving smaller
broadcasters, including minority and
women owners, from the marketplace?
How would viewpoint diversity and
localism be affected? The Incubator
Order rewards successful incubation of
a radio station with one waiver per
market to exceed the applicable
ownership limit by one station and
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:17 Feb 27, 2019
Jkt 247001
allows participants to use no more than
one reward waiver per market. NAB
submitted its proposal to maintain the
eight-station limit for the top 75 Nielsen
Audio Metro markets before the
Commission adopted the Incubator
Order, so it is unclear whether NAB is
suggesting that successful incubation of
one station should result in a waiver for
two stations or successful incubation of
two stations should entitle an owner to
acquire two stations above the limit
within the same market. The
Commission seeks comment on both
possible interpretations.
15. AM/FM Subcaps. In the 2010/2014
Quadrennial Review Order, the
Commission retained the Local Radio
Ownership Rule’s AM/FM subcaps,
which prevent a broadcaster from
owning more than five AM or five FM
stations in markets in the largest market
tier, four AM or four FM stations in
markets in the two middle-sized tiers, or
three AM or three FM stations in
markets in the smallest tier. The
Commission seeks comment on whether
the AM/FM subcaps remain necessary
and whether its previous reasons for
maintaining subcaps are still valid. For
example, have subcaps promoted
market entry? Are subcaps still
necessary given the Commission’s
efforts to revitalize AM radio or has the
disparity between the FM and AM
services been narrowed to an extent that
the subcaps could be relaxed or
eliminated? Since its 2010/2014
Quadrennial Review, the Commission
has granted over 1,000 applications to
acquire and relocate FM translators to
rebroadcast AM stations. Should the
expanded and improved coverage of
those AM stations affect the analysis of
subcaps? Conversely, data from the
2010/2014 Quadrennial Review
indicated that the transition to digital
radio actually exacerbated the divide
between the services because AM
stations have been slower to adopt
digital radio technology. What is the
import of the current status of the digital
radio transition for evaluating the
subcaps? If subcaps continue to promote
competition or ownership diversity, or
otherwise serve the public interest, are
they currently set at the appropriate
levels?
16. If the Commission revises the
Local Radio Ownership Rule, should the
modified rule include AM or FM
subcaps, and if so, how should they be
applied? NAB’s proposal essentially
would eliminate AM subcaps in all
markets and retain FM subcaps in only
the top 75 markets. NAB does not
explain why it would distinguish the
FM service for restricted ownership in
the top markets rather than limit the
PO 00000
Frm 00040
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
total number of radio stations in those
markets regardless of service, and the
Commission seeks comment on whether
the proposal is supported by technical
or marketplace differences between the
services. In a letter filed shortly after
NAB submitted its proposal, the owner
of a network of AM stations argued that
removing and/or relaxing FM subcaps
would harm the AM service by
facilitating the migration of content to
the FM service. Concurring with that
view, iHeartMedia urges the
Commission to loosen restrictions on
AM ownership while retaining the
existing FM subcaps, arguing that doing
so would be consistent with the
Commission’s efforts to revitalize AM
radio. Considering these competing
positions, the Commission seeks
comment on what limits, if any, should
apply to AM and FM ownership,
whether to retain the current market
size tiers and numerical limits, and on
whether and how any proposed
revisions to the Local Radio Ownership
Rule should include such limits.
17. Embedded Markets. Owners of
radio stations in embedded markets
within a parent market, which currently
exist only in New York and Washington,
DC, must comply with the Local Radio
Ownership Rule’s numerical limits for
both the embedded market and the
parent market. In response to the 2010/
2014 Quadrennial Review Further
Notice of Proposed Rulemaking
(FNPRM), Connoisseur Media argued
that because radio stations within
different embedded markets within a
parent market have little or no contour
overlap and may reach different
populations, the Commission’s analysis
of a proposed acquisition in one
embedded market should not include
stations owned in the other embedded
markets within the same parent market.
In the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review
Order on Reconsideration, the
Commission declined to adopt an
across-the-board change to its embedded
market methodology, but adopted a
waiver standard whereby embedded
market transactions in markets with
multiple embedded markets would be
presumed to be in the public interest if
they met a two-prong test proposed by
Connoisseur: (1) As with the
Commission’s current methodology for
embedded markets, a radio station
owner seeking a rule waiver must
comply with the applicable numerical
ownership limit in each embedded
market using the Nielsen Audio Metro
methodology; and (2) instead of then
also demonstrating compliance with the
applicable numerical ownership limit
based on the Commission’s parent
E:\FR\FM\28FEP1.SGM
28FEP1
khammond on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with PROPOSALS
Federal Register / Vol. 84, No. 40 / Thursday, February 28, 2019 / Proposed Rules
market analysis, the applicant must
show that it also complies with the
ownership limits as determined by the
contour-overlap methodology ordinarily
applicable in undefined markets. The
Commission adopted this presumptive
waiver standard on an interim basis
pending the outcome of this 2018
Quadrennial Review proceeding.
18. Accordingly, the Commission
seeks comment on how to address the
issue of embedded market transactions.
If the Commission retains a Local Radio
Ownership Rule, how should it apply
going forward to radios station in
markets that contain multiple embedded
markets, currently New York and
Washington, DC? Should the
presumptive waiver standard become
permanent? Should it be modified in
any way? Should it apply to all current
and future markets that contain multiple
embedded markets, or should its
application be limited to the two
existing parent markets with multiple
embedded markets? How do
competition, diversity, and localism
considerations affect the question?
Embedded market designations can be
updated and modified by Nielsen Audio
as market conditions change, and
Nielsen Audio’s radio station customers
can request the designation of a new
embedded market. How could the
Commission guard against purchasers
taking advantage of an anticipated
designation of a new embedded market
in a manner that would thwart the
purpose of the current ownership
limits? For example, in the event that
Nielsen Audio creates new, additional
situations with multiple embedded
markets within a larger parent market,
should there be a waiting period before
applicants can take advantage of that
change in circumstance, similar to the
waiting period applicable to changes in
the stations reported as ‘‘home’’ to a
Nielsen Audio Metro market? If the
Commission adopts any change to its
approach to embedded markets, should
the change also apply to markets with
a single embedded market? Is there a
distinction between markets with one
embedded market and markets with
multiple embedded markets such that
the Commission should vary its
approach between those situations?
19. In the 2010/2014 Quadrennial
Review Order on Reconsideration, the
Commission expressed its intent to
consider in this 2018 Quadrennial
Review an alternate NAB proposal that
stations licensed in embedded markets
with signal coverage of less than 50
percent of the parent market’s
population not be considered part of the
parent market for purposes of local
ownership limit compliance
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:17 Feb 27, 2019
Jkt 247001
calculations. The Commission seeks
comment on whether it should adopt
such an approach or any other acrossthe-board rule changes regarding
embedded markets. Is there a need to
implement a rule change that carves out
a blanket exception to the current
methodology given that there are only
two parent markets containing multiple
embedded markets? Or is a permanent
presumptive waiver standard an
adequate solution given how narrow its
use is likely to be? The Commission
seeks comment on the potential
advantages and disadvantages of these
various approaches and invites
proposals for other ways to address
embedded market transactions.
20. Minority and Female Ownership.
In the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review
Order, the Commission found the
current Local Radio Ownership Rule to
be consistent with its goal of promoting
minority and female ownership of
broadcast radio stations, observing that
the rule, while competition-based,
indirectly promotes viewpoint diversity
by facilitating ‘‘the presence of
independently owned broadcast radio
stations in the local market, thereby
increasing the likelihood of a variety of
viewpoints and preserving ownership
opportunities for new entrants.’’ It
pointed to AM subcaps in particular as
elements of the rule that foster new
entry. Because available data did not
show that stricter limits would increase
minority and female radio ownership,
however, the Commission chose not to
tighten the rule. Similarly, the
Commission found no indication of a
causal link between Congress’ loosening
of local radio limits in 1996 and the
increase in ownership diversity since
then that would justify loosening the
rules. The Commission seeks comment
on whether any new information has
become available that would cause us to
reevaluate these conclusions. The
Commission also seeks comment on
how retaining or modifying the Local
Radio Ownership Rule might affect
broadcast radio ownership and entry by
small business owners, if at all.
21. Local Television Ownership Rule.
The Local Television Ownership Rule
allows an entity to own up to two
television stations in the same Nielsen
Designated Market Area (DMA) (a group
of counties forming an exclusive
geographic area to which the Nielsen
Company assigns each broadcast
television station) if: (1) The digital
noise limited service contours (NLSCs)
of the stations (as determined by
§ 73.622(e) of the Commission’s rules)
do not overlap; or (2) at the time the
application to acquire or construct the
station(s) is filed, at least one of the
PO 00000
Frm 00041
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
6745
stations is not ranked among the topfour stations in the DMA, based on the
most recent all-day (9 a.m.–midnight)
audience share, as measured by Nielsen
Media Research or by any comparable
professional, accepted audience ratings
service. With respect to the latter
provision—the Top-Four Prohibition—
an applicant may request that the
Commission examine the facts and
circumstances in a market regarding a
particular transaction and, based on the
showing made by the applicant in a
particular case, make a finding that
permitting an entity to directly or
indirectly own, operate, or control two
top-four television stations licensed in
the same DMA would serve the public
interest, convenience, and necessity.
The Commission considers showings
that the Top-Four Prohibition should
not apply due to specific circumstances
in a local market or with respect to a
specific transaction on a case-by-case
basis.
22. The Commission found in the
2018 Quadrennial Review Order on
Reconsideration that local television
ownership limits remained necessary to
promote competition among broadcast
stations in local television markets,
finding that such competition leads
stations to invest in better and more
locally tailored programming and to
compete for advertising revenue and
retransmission consent fees. The
Commission also determined, however,
that the existing rule required
modification to ensure that television
broadcasters could achieve efficiencies
to make such improvements in an
evolving video marketplace. The
Commission therefore repealed the
provision of the previous rule requiring
at least eight independently owned
television stations to remain in a DMA
after any station acquisition in the
DMA, finding that this Eight-Voices test
was unsupported by the record or
reasoned analysis and was no longer
necessary in the public interest. The
Commission also added flexibility to the
application of the Top-Four Prohibition
by adopting the case-by-case analysis
mentioned above.
23. First, the Commission seeks
comment on whether the current
version of the Local Television
Ownership Rule is necessary in the
public interest as a result of
competition. In earlier media ownership
reviews, broadcasters argued that local
television ownership restrictions
prevent them from competing
effectively, while other commenters
supported retention of limits based on
the need to prevent excessive
consolidation of television stations due
to the unique nature of their free, over-
E:\FR\FM\28FEP1.SGM
28FEP1
khammond on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with PROPOSALS
6746
Federal Register / Vol. 84, No. 40 / Thursday, February 28, 2019 / Proposed Rules
the-air programming provided on
spectrum licensed for public benefit.
The Commission seeks comment on
how developments in the video
programming industry since the last
quadrennial review have affected
whether the Local Television
Ownership Rule is necessary as a result
of competition and to promote localism
and viewpoint diversity among local
broadcast television stations. The
Commission seeks comment on whether
promoting competition among
television stations in local viewing
markets continues to be the proper
framework within which to consider the
rule, and if so, what forms of
competition it should take into account
under such a framework. For instance,
how, if at all, should the Commission
consider competition among television
stations for viewers, advertisers,
retransmission consent fees, network
affiliation, the provision of local news
or other programming, the production or
acquisition of programming, innovation,
or any other form of competition?
24. The Commission also seeks
comment on whether the Local
Television Ownership Rule is necessary
to promote localism or viewpoint
diversity. The Commission has
previously stated that a competitionbased rule, while not designed
specifically to promote localism or
viewpoint diversity, may still have such
an effect. Has the prior reliance on
competition as the primary policy goal
of the Local Television Ownership Rule
also served as a proxy for preserving a
certain level of localism or viewpoint
diversity in local television markets that
might otherwise be lost were we to find
the rule no longer necessary for
competition purposes?
25. The Commission seeks comment
on whether a competition-based Local
Television Ownership Rule promotes
the production or provision of local
programming. Localism has been a
cornerstone of the Commission’s
broadcast regulation for decades, with
the Commission finding that broadcast
licensees have an obligation to air
programming that is responsive to the
needs and interests of their
communities of license. Does promoting
competition among broadcast stations
incentivize stations to produce and
improve local programming? Could or
does competition from non-broadcast
video sources, which have no local
programming requirements, create the
same incentives to produce and improve
local programming?
26. If the Commission decides to
retain the Local Television Ownership
Rule, it will analyze the relevant parts
of the rule to examine whether each
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:17 Feb 27, 2019
Jkt 247001
particular provision similarly remains
necessary in the public interest as a
result of competition or whether it
should be modified or eliminated. Thus,
the Commission seeks comment on
specific aspects of the rule’s operation,
including the relevant product market,
numerical limits, and the Top-Four
Prohibition, to assess whether these
subparts remain necessary or whether
any or all of them should be modified
or eliminated. The Commission also
asks whether developments in the video
programming industry involving
multicasting, satellite stations, low
power stations, and the next generation
transmission standard have any
implications on the Local Television
Ownership Rule or its subparts.
27. Market Definition. In the 2010/
2014 Quadrennial Review Order on
Reconsideration, the Commission found
that a rule to preserve competition
among local broadcast television
stations was still warranted, but also
noted that it was not free to retain the
rule without adjustments to account for
marketplace changes outside the local
broadcast television market. The
Commission also found that nonbroadcast video offerings do not serve as
meaningful substitutes for local
broadcast television, and noted that
video programming delivered by
multichannel video programming
distributors (MVPDs) is generally
uniform across all markets, as is
programming provided by online video
distributors (OVDs). The Commission
stated that unlike local broadcast
stations, MVPDs and OVDs were not
likely to make programming decisions
based on conditions or preferences in
local markets, but indicated that this
conclusion could change in a future
proceeding with a different record.
28. The Commission now seeks
comment on relevant marketplace
changes and whether and how it should
take such changes into account. The
Commission seeks comment on the
appropriate product market for
reviewing the Local Television
Ownership Rule, including whether to
include more than broadcast video
programming and what market
participants to consider. In light of the
evolving video marketplace, the
Commission also seeks comment on its
prior findings in the 2010/2014
Quadrennial Review Order, and whether
and to what extent non-broadcast
sources of video programming should be
considered competitors to broadcast
television stations. Do consumers
consider broadcast television to be
interchangeable with other sources of
programming? If so, what other sources
of video programming should be
PO 00000
Frm 00042
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
included in the analysis of a local
product market? What factors should
the Commission consider in analyzing
non-broadcast sources of video
programming? Should the Commission
distinguish between linear (scheduled)
and non-linear (i.e., video-on-demand)
distributors of video? In which product
markets, if any, do non-broadcast video
programmers compete with broadcast
television programmers? Does broadcast
television offer any programming for
which there is no substitute available
from non-broadcast video programmers?
Based on Nielsen and NAB data, the
Commission noted in the Eighteenth
Video Competition Report the
increasing number of households
relying on broadcast rather than MVPD
service. To what extent do consumers
rely on broadcast television as their
primary, or only, source of video
programming? The Commission
previously noted that broadband
penetration is relevant when
considering whether on-line platforms
are meaningful substitutes for local
broadcast. Is the availability of nonbroadcast video comparable to that of
broadcast television? Do viewers rely on
or consume programming from local
broadcast stations in a manner different
from other sources of, potentially, nonlocal video programming? In addition,
do any non-broadcast video
programmers make programming
decisions based on local markets or the
actions of individual local television
stations (i.e., a cable operator deciding
to carry local sporting events not
covered by the local broadcaster)?
29. The Commission also found in the
2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Order
that arguments by broadcasters that
advertisers no longer distinguish
between local broadcast television and
non-broadcast video programming when
deciding how to spend on local
advertising were not supported by the
record. Thus, the Commission seeks
comment on whether and to what extent
non-broadcast sources of video
programming should be considered
competitors to broadcast television
stations. The Commission also asks how
advertisers select between local
broadcast and non-broadcast sources of
programming and seeks studies and data
that it can use to assess substitutability
in local advertising among all sources of
video in a DMA. The Commission seeks
comment and new data about whether
and how various video programming
providers compete for local advertising
revenue.
30. Given the Commission’s prior
findings in the 2010/2014 Biennial
Review Order that competition within
local markets can produce better
E:\FR\FM\28FEP1.SGM
28FEP1
khammond on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with PROPOSALS
Federal Register / Vol. 84, No. 40 / Thursday, February 28, 2019 / Proposed Rules
programming and programming tailored
to local needs and interests from which
viewers benefit, the Commission seeks
comment on whether, in evaluating the
Local Television Ownership Rule, it
should consider sources of local news
and other local programming as a
relevant product market. What are the
most prominent sources of local news
and local programming beyond
broadcast television? Should non-video
providers of news and information—
such as radio, newspapers, internet
websites, and social media platforms—
be examined in the product market
analysis? To what extent do potential
viewers rely for local news on these
alternative sources? Given Knight
Foundation reports that online-only
local news websites have limited
impact, are these sources originators of
local programming, or do they simply
aggregate or utilize content generated by
traditional local news sources? Are nonbroadcast sources of local programming
available in all DMAs or are they just in
major markets? Is the depth of any
coverage of local issues by nonbroadcast platforms consistent across
DMAs? The Commission seeks comment
on the availability and variety of local
video programming in each Nielsen
DMA and on how the Commission
would, and if it should, evaluate local
programming for purposes of any
programming-based analysis. The
Commission seeks comment on whether
defining the local product market for
our television ownership rules to
include specific types of programming
would raise First Amendment concerns.
31. What measures could the
Commission use to assess competition
among sources of local video
programming or other local content?
What data sources might the
Commission use to determine which
sources consumers consider substitutes?
Given the lack of a single, accepted,
industry-wide standard for measuring
online viewership, how should the
Commission account for various
providers of news, information, and
video programming to the extent that
some entities, such as OVDs and
websites, may lack an industry standard
for measuring viewership and
engagement?
32. The Commission also seeks
comment on the relationship between
its local television ownership market
definition and any changes thereto, and
the market definition and analysis used
by DOJ, which examines local television
broadcasters competing in the spot
advertising market. The Commission
stated in the 2010/2014 Quadrennial
Review Order that its market definition
when evaluating broadcast television
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:17 Feb 27, 2019
Jkt 247001
mergers is like DOJ’s in that the scope
of the Commission’s rule is similarly
limited to local television broadcast
stations. DOJ’s analysis, however, has
historically focused on competition for
advertising, whereas the Commission’s
analysis focuses on multiple factors,
including audience share. Recently in
evaluating the combination of Nexstar
and Media General, DOJ also looked at
competition for retransmission consent
licensing fees in local television
markets. The Commission seeks
comment on whether and how DOJ’s
analytical framework should inform its
own, and vice versa. Are there ways in
which the Commission’s current rule is
either consistent or inconsistent with
antitrust principles? Do other public
interest considerations support the rule?
33. Numerical Limit. Currently, a
broadcast licensee can own up to two
television stations (a duopoly) in a
DMA, subject to the requirements of the
Local Television Ownership Rule. In the
2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Order,
the Commission concluded that changes
in the local television market
demonstrated by the record were
insufficient to justify either tightening
or loosening this numerical limit. The
Commission therefore seeks comment
on whether subsequent changes in the
video programming industry now
support changes to the numerical limit.
If the Commission finds that retaining a
local television rule remains in the
public interest, should it change the
numerical limit on how many stations
may be owned in a DMA?
34. Top-Four Prohibition. The
Commission found in the 2010/2014
Quadrennial Review Order that ratings
data supported the Local Television
Ownership Rule’s focus on the top-four
rated full power television stations in a
market, that there typically remained a
significant ‘‘cushion’’ of audience share
points that separated the top-four
stations in a market from the fifthranked station and below, and that the
record supported potential harms
associated with top-four combinations.
The Commission seeks comment on the
applicability of these previous
conclusions based on new, updated
ratings data and/or examples of existing
commonly owned top-four station
combinations. If the Commission retains
a local television ownership rule,
should the top four prohibition be
retained or modified?
35. In the 2010/2014 Quadrennial
Review Order on Reconsideration, the
Commission recognized that rigid
application of the Top-Four Prohibition
in all DMAs may not be supported by
the unique conditions present in certain
DMAs or with respect to certain
PO 00000
Frm 00043
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
6747
transactions, and accordingly adopted a
hybrid approach to allow applicants to
seek a case-by-case examination of a
proposed combination that would
otherwise be prohibited by the Top-Four
Prohibition. The Commission stated that
the types of information applicants
could provide on competition in the
local market in such examinations
included: (1) Ratings share data of the
stations proposed to be combined
compared with other stations in the
market; (2) revenue share data of the
stations proposed to be combined
compared with other stations in the
market, including advertising (on-air
and digital) and retransmission consent
fees; (3) market characteristics, such as
population and the number and types of
broadcast television stations serving the
market (including any strong
competitors outside the top-four rated
broadcast television stations); (4) the
likely effects on programming meeting
the needs and interests of the
community; and (5) any other
circumstances impacting the market,
particularly any disparities primarily
impacting small and mid-sized markets.
36. The Commission asks whether
flexibility in applying the Top-Four
prohibition remains necessary and, if so,
whether the case-by-case approach is
the most effective way to achieve it. If
the Commission finds that a case-bycase analysis is the best approach, do
the types of information listed in the
2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Order
on Reconsideration serve as reliable
factors in determining whether a topfour combination would serve the
public interest? If so, should some
factors be weighed more heavily than
others in the analysis? Are there factors
in addition to the examples provided in
the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review
Order on Reconsideration that the
Commission should consider? What
kinds of data should licensees provide
to support their showings? Should the
Commission adopt a more rigid set of
criteria for its case-by-case
determination?
37. Alternatively, should the
Commission avoid a case-by-case or
hybrid approach and establish a brightline test that would permit common
ownership of two top-four stations in all
cases, or in particular markets or
circumstances? For example, should the
Commission permit common ownership
of the fourth-ranked station in a market
and either the second-ranked station or
third-ranked station in that same
market? Should the Commission allow
combinations between the secondranked station or third-ranked station in
the same market? Should such
combinations only be permitted in
E:\FR\FM\28FEP1.SGM
28FEP1
khammond on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with PROPOSALS
6748
Federal Register / Vol. 84, No. 40 / Thursday, February 28, 2019 / Proposed Rules
smaller markets where there is less
advertising revenue available to support
programming and station operations?
The Commission also seeks comment on
whether it should create a presumption
for permitting common ownership of
two top-four stations if certain
conditions are met. What conditions
should the Commission consider in
determining if a combination would not
negatively impact competition? For
example, should the Commission
presume that a combination is
permissible if the combined stations’
share of the audience and/or advertising
market share does not exceed a certain
threshold?
38. If the Commission either retains
the case-by-case approach or adopts a
bright-line test, it seeks comment on
how to analyze competition in local
television markets. In considering the
effect of top-four combinations on local
advertising markets, the Commission
seeks studies that estimate the elasticity
of demand for local advertising. In the
absence of such studies, what data
sources or types of data might the
Commission use to assess
substitutability in local advertising
across dayparts, program types, and
stations? What measures, in addition to
viewership share, could be used to
assess competition between stations in
local programming? What data sources
might we use to determine which
programs or stations viewers consider
substitutes?
39. A top-four combination may have
different effects on competition among
broadcast stations for viewers of
different types of programming, for
instance, local programming, network
programming, and syndicated
programming. Should the Commission
weigh each competitive effect and, if so,
how? If the Commission considers
specific categories of programming,
should it look at the viewership of each
type of programming, the amount of
revenue generated for the local station
by each type of programming, both, or
something else? Top-four combinations
may also affect the quantity or quality
of local programming available in the
market. Although intended primarily to
promote competition, does the Top-Four
Prohibition also preserve, as a
byproduct, a sufficient level of localism
or viewpoint diversity in local markets?
The Commission seeks comment on
whether and how it should consider
elimination of an independent local
news operation or a reduction in local
news programming.
40. The Commission also seeks
comment on whether and how it should
weigh any effect on retransmission
consent negotiations in evaluating
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:17 Feb 27, 2019
Jkt 247001
competitive effects under the
Commission’s case-by-case approach to
evaluating top-four station
combinations. Commenters in
proceedings involving potential top-four
station combinations consistently have
raised the issue of potential
retransmission consent fee increases
because of reduced competition
between stations and undue bargaining
leverage for stations if commonly owned
top-four stations are able to negotiate
such fees jointly as a result of the
combination. In its Nexstar-Media
General review, DOJ also recognized
that common ownership of two major
broadcast network affiliates can lead to
diminished competition in the
negotiation of retransmission
agreements with MVPDs in local
television markets. The Commission
therefore seeks comment on whether
and how it should weigh the effect on
retransmission consent negotiations in
evaluating top-four station combinations
under its case-by-case approach. Should
the Commission maintain the Top-Four
Prohibition for purposes of preventing
any potential competitive harms caused
by joint negotiation of retransmission
consent fees by two commonly owned
top-four stations in a DMA, and would
such an approach be inconsistent with
congressional intent in prohibiting joint
negotiation only when conducted by
non-commonly owned stations in the
STELA Reauthorization Act of 2014?
41. If the Commission keeps the TopFour Prohibition or a similar rule that
relies on the ranking of stations by
audience share or viewership, should
any specific provisions of the rule be
modified? The rule currently determines
a station’s in-market ranking based on
the most recent all-day (9 a.m.–
midnight) audience share, as measured
by Nielsen Media Research. The
Commission seeks comment on whether
this data point is still the most useful for
accurately determining a station’s
ranking for purposes of the Top-Four
Prohibition. Have there been changes in
the industry that necessitate examining
different data? The Commission also
seeks comment on whether and how it
should account for instances where a
station makes use of multicast streams,
satellite stations, or translators. Should
the ratings of these stations or streams
be combined with the ratings of the
primary station or stream to determine
the station’s ratings in the DMA? Why
or why not? Lastly, based on
Commission staff review of Nielsen
data, there are instances where
noncommercial television stations have
audience shares comparable to those of
commercial stations. Should the
PO 00000
Frm 00044
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
Commission distinguish between
commercial and noncommercial stations
for purposes of the Top-Four
Prohibition? Why or why not?
42. The Commission seeks comment
on whether to provide clarification of
the phrase ‘‘at the time the application
to acquire or construct the station(s) is
filed.’’ Should entities filing an
application submit as support audience
share data for the most recent month,
week, or sweeps period in relation to
the date when the application was
submitted to the Commission? Should
the time frame for the submitted data be
required to show a longer period? For
example, should the Commission
require applicants to submit ratings data
over a three-year period to demonstrate
that a station truly is or is not ranked
among the top-four stations in the DMA
‘‘at the time the application to acquire
or construct the station(s) is filed’’ as
suggested in the 2010/2014 Quadrennial
Review Order on Reconsideration? If
not, should the Commission take
another approach to prevent
circumvention of the Top-Four
Prohibition’s requirements based on
anomalous data? Should it rely on the
most recent period solely as a
presumption, which might be rebutted
by interested parties?
43. Given the longstanding nature of
the Top-Four Prohibition, much of the
discussion in this section focuses on the
continued applicability of that rule and
ways that it might be adjusted or
clarified to apply in the current video
marketplace. The Commission also
seeks comment on alternatives to the
Top-Four Prohibition. Should common
ownership of two stations in a market be
permitted when at least one of the
stations is not ranked among the topthree stations in the market, or among
the top-two? What economic data
support establishing such a top-three
approach, considering the significant
differences in national audience share
between the top-four national networks
and others? Should the Commission
distinguish between stations located in
larger Nielsen DMAs and those in midto small-sized DMAs by adopting a
tiered approach to application of any
ranking-based prohibition? Should
common ownership be permitted when
there is a certain number of nonbroadcast local video programing
sources in a DMA? The Commission
seeks comment on how these and any
other proposals supported by the record
would promote and protect competition
in local television markets.
44. Multicasting. As a result of the
digital television transition, all fullpower television stations have the
ability to use their available spectrum to
E:\FR\FM\28FEP1.SGM
28FEP1
khammond on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with PROPOSALS
Federal Register / Vol. 84, No. 40 / Thursday, February 28, 2019 / Proposed Rules
broadcast not only their main program
stream but also, if they choose,
additional program streams—an activity
commonly referred to as multicasting. In
the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review
Order the Commission distinguished
between the ability to multicast and
ownership of a separate broadcast
station and declined to impose
restrictions on local television station
ownership based on the ability to
multicast. Because the record indicated
that dual affiliations involving two Big
Four networks (ABC, CBS, Fox, and
NBC) via multicasting were generally
limited to smaller markets where there
was an insufficient number of fullpower commercial television stations to
accommodate each Big Four network or
where other unique marketplace factors
led to creating the dual affiliation, the
Commission declined to regulate dual
affiliations through multicasting, even
in instances where a licensee is
affiliated with more than one of the Big
Four networks. The Commission stated,
however, that it would continue to
monitor this issue and act in the future,
if appropriate.
45. The Commission now seeks
comment on how technical and other
developments in the broadcast industry
have affected multicasting. Are some
multicast streams functioning as the
equivalent of separate broadcast
stations? Multicasting has enabled
broadcasters to bring more programming
to consumers, particularly in smaller,
rural markets, by expanding the
availability of the four major networks
and newer networks. Based on
Commission staff review of Nielsen
data, there are at least several dozen
DMAs where a single entity holds
affiliations with two Big Four networks
by using a multicast stream to carry the
second signal. Thus, the Commission
seeks comment on the characteristics of
DMAs where major network affiliations
are carried on multicast streams. Are
there certain markets where this
practice is more commonplace? Do dual
affiliations with major networks remains
limited to smaller markets or has the
practice become more widespread? The
Commission asks whether and how it
should evaluate multicast streams for
purposes of the Local Television
Ownership Rule.
46. Satellite Stations. Television
satellite stations are full-power
broadcast stations authorized under Part
73 of the Commission’s rules that
generally retransmit some or all of the
programming of another television
station, known as the parent station,
which typically is commonly owned or
operated with the satellite station.
Satellite stations are exempt from the
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:17 Feb 27, 2019
Jkt 247001
Local Television Ownership Rule, and
the Commission seeks comment on their
use to carry two Big Four networks in
a market. For instance, how should the
Commission treat a situation in which a
licensee utilizes multicasting to air two
Big Four networks on a parent station
(e.g., one on the primary stream and one
on a multicast stream), and airs the
same two Big Four networks on a
satellite station? How prevalent is this
practice, and is it consistent with the
purposes behind allowing satellite
stations in the first place, which are
generally intended to bring over-the-air
television service to unserved areas? Are
there benefits to allowing this practice
that outweigh any potential harms? The
Commission seeks comment on whether
this issue should be addressed through
modification of the satellite exemption
to the Local Television Ownership Rule
or, alternatively, in the context of the
satellite authorization process.
47. Low Power Television Stations.
Changes in industry practice and
technological advances may have
extended the reach and enhanced the
capabilities of low power and translator
television broadcast stations that are
currently exempt from local television
ownership limits. Based on a review of
Nielsen data by Commission staff, there
are a significant number of low power
stations affiliated with a Big Four
network. Because of this affiliation,
MVPDs are likely willing to carry the
low power stations, which qualify for
must-carry on cable systems under very
limited circumstances, despite their
status. If low power stations can in this
way become the functional equivalent of
full power stations in certain instances,
should the Commission account for the
number of low power television stations
as part of its Local Television
Ownership Rule in some way, and if so,
how? For instance, should a low power
station that is ranked among the top four
stations in audience share in a DMA be
counted as a top-four station for
purposes of the Top-Four Prohibition?
48. Next Generation Broadcast
Television Transmission Standard.
Currently, the broadcast television
industry is developing a new
transmission standard called Advanced
Television Systems Committee (ATSC)
3.0 with the intent of merging the
capabilities of over-the-air broadcasting
with the broadband viewing and
information delivery methods of the
internet, using the same 6 MHz
channels presently allocated for DTV
service. According to ATSC 3.0
advocates, the new standard has the
potential to improve broadcast signal
reception greatly, particularly on mobile
devices and television receivers without
PO 00000
Frm 00045
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
6749
outdoor antennas. ATSC 3.0 will enable
broadcasters to offer enhanced and
innovative new features to consumers,
including Ultra High Definition (UHD)
picture and immersive audio, more
localized programming content, an
advanced emergency alert system (EAS)
capable of waking up sleeping devices
to warn consumers of imminent
emergencies, better accessibility
options, and interactive services.
49. The Commission seeks comment
on the implications, if any, of the new
broadcast television transmission
standard on the Local Television
Ownership Rule. The Commission also
seeks comment on whether any
provisions of the Local Television
Ownership Rule potentially could affect
adoption and deployment of the new
transmission standard. How, if at all,
should the Commission in the context of
local television ownership consider the
decisions of television broadcasters to
adopt voluntarily the ATSC 3.0
transmission standard?
50. Broadcast Spectrum Auction. In
the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review
Order, the Commission stated that it
could not yet determine how the
incentive auction would affect the Local
Television Ownership Rule. On April
13, 2017, the Commission released a
public notice announcing the results of
the reverse and forward auctions and
the repacking of the broadcast television
spectrum. Pursuant to the statute
authorizing the incentive auction, that
public notice marked the auction’s
completion and the start of the 39month post-auction transition period.
Given completion of the auction and the
subsequent surrender of spectrum and/
or initiation of channel-sharing
agreements, the Commission seeks
comment on whether the auction’s
effects on local television ownership
have any implication on retention or
modification of the Local Television
Ownership Rule.
51. Shared Service Agreements. In the
2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Order,
the Commission adopted a definition of
shared service agreements (SSAs) and,
despite opposition from broadcasters, a
requirement that commercial television
stations disclose SSAs by placing them
in their online public inspection files.
The Commission also found it lacked
knowledge about the content, scope,
and prevalence of SSAs that kept it from
evaluating the impact of these
agreements, if any, on its policy goals
with respect to broadcast ownership.
The 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review
Order on Reconsideration upheld the
disclosure requirement, which took
effect on March 23, 2018. The
Commission now seeks comment on
E:\FR\FM\28FEP1.SGM
28FEP1
khammond on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with PROPOSALS
6750
Federal Register / Vol. 84, No. 40 / Thursday, February 28, 2019 / Proposed Rules
what action, if any, it should take on
SSAs in the context of this 2018 review
of the Local Television Ownership Rule.
Should the Commission retain or
eliminate the SSA filing requirement?
What, if anything, have commenters
learned from filing the agreements so
far?
52. Minority and Female Ownership.
The Commission stated in the 2010/
2014 Quadrennial Order that, while the
Local Television Ownership Rule
promotes competition among broadcast
television stations in local markets and
is not meant to preserve or create
specific amounts of minority and female
ownership, the rule nevertheless
promotes opportunities for diversity in
local television ownership. The
Commission concluded that the
competition-based rule helps to ensure
the presence of independently owned
broadcast television stations in the local
market, thereby indirectly increasing the
likelihood of a variety of viewpoints and
preserving ownership opportunities for
new entrants. The record held no data
indicating that the duopoly rule has
reduced minority ownership or
suggested that a return to the single
station per licensee rule would increase
ownership opportunities for minorities
and women. While the data did indicate
an increase in minority ownership
following relaxation of the Local
Television Ownership Rule, there was
no evidence in the record that
established a causal connection. The
Commission now asks how retaining,
modifying, or eliminating the local
television rule would affect broadcast
television ownership and entry by
minority and female owners, if at all.
The Commission seeks data and an
updated record on the effects of the
Local Television Ownership Rule on
minority and female broadcast
ownership and entry. Finally, the
Commission seeks comment on how
retaining or modifying the rule might
affect broadcast television ownership
and entry by small business owners, if
at all.
53. Dual Network Rule. The Dual
Network Rule permits common
ownership of multiple broadcast
networks, but effectively prohibits a
merger between or among the Big Four
networks. In the 2010/2014 Quadrennial
Review Order, the Commission
concluded that the Dual Network Rule
continues to be necessary in the public
interest to promote competition and
localism. With respect to competition,
the Commission found the rule
necessary to promote both competition
in the provision of primetime
entertainment programming and the sale
of national advertising. With respect to
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:17 Feb 27, 2019
Jkt 247001
localism, the Commission found that the
rule was necessary to preserve the
balance of power between the Big Four
networks and their local affiliates.
54. In conducting its analysis of
whether the Dual Network Rule remains
necessary, the Commission traditionally
has considered broadcast networks as
participating in the video marketplace
in two ways: (1) Assembling and
distributing a collection of programming
suitable for large, national audiences,
and (2) selling advertising based on this
programming to large, national
advertisers. Does the Dual Network Rule
continue to be relevant to competition
or network behavior in either or both of
these segments? The Commission
concluded in the 2010/2014
Quadrennial Review Order that ‘‘the
primetime entertainment programming
provided by the Big Four broadcast
networks and national television
advertising time are each a distinct
product—the availability, price, and
quality of which could be restricted, to
the detriment of consumers, if two [Big
Four broadcast networks] were
permitted to merge.’’ Does this
conclusion remain valid? The
Commission also generally seeks
comment on whether the Dual Network
Rule remains necessary to promote its
goals of competition, viewpoint
diversity and localism, and on whether
the benefits of the rule outweigh any
costs.
55. Regarding viewership, in the
2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Order
the Commission found, based on
Nielsen data, that no cable programming
could deliver primetime audiences on
par with, let alone greater than, the
primetime audiences delivered by the
Big Four networks. The Commission’s
Eighteenth Video Competition Report,
based on 2015 data, showed that
broadcast affiliates still draw the largest
share of total day and prime time
viewing audiences in relation to
independent stations and noncommercial and cable networks. The
2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Order
also found a continued wide disparity
in the advertising rates and revenue
earned by the Big Four networks and
other broadcast and cable networks. The
Commission seeks more current data on
these topics. Do these or other recent
developments have any implications for
the Commission’s competition rationale
underlying the Dual Network Rule?
56. The Commission also found in the
2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Order
and in previous reviews of the Dual
Network Rule that the Big Four
networks operate as a ‘‘strategic group’’
in the national advertising market and
that they largely compete among
PO 00000
Frm 00046
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
themselves for the most significant
portion of the national advertising
market, namely advertisers that seek to
reach national mass audiences. The
Commission further found that the
programming provided by the Big Four
networks was a distinct product that,
when compared to other broadcast and
cable programming, had a unique ability
to regularly attract large prime-time
audiences and thus command higher
advertising rates. Does the
Commission’s ‘‘strategic group’’ finding
still hold true? Given the increasing
number of video programmers in today’s
market, as well as the increasing
popularity of their programming, is
network broadcast programming still a
distinct product? Does nightly network
news programming, or any other
programming, distinguish the broadcast
networks, or are consumers now turning
to other news or programming sources
that remove this distinction? Are there
other producers of mass audience
programming such that a merger
between two of the Big Four networks
would no longer harm competition for
national advertising? In the past, the
Commission reviewed programming
audience shares and the advertising
rates and revenues of various
programmers in making this
determination. Should the Commission
continue to rely on these data, or are
there other data or metrics it should
consider? Are there better sources of
relevant data than the Commission has
considered in the past?
57. One of the biggest changes in the
video programming market has been
online distribution of programming
from a variety of sources. Today,
OVDs—including linear multichannel
streaming services, both those from
social media companies and other
online platforms, and direct-toconsumer offerings by broadcast
networks themselves—reach millions of
consumers. Digital advertising on these
or other online platforms is steadily
increasing in market and revenue share.
How, if at all, have these changes
affected competition for national
broadcast television advertising? The
Commission seeks comment on whether
and how any such changes should affect
our Dual Network Rule.
58. The Commission also seeks
comment on whether recent
developments in the video programming
and national advertising markets suggest
that the Dual Network Rule should be
modified to promote competition or
eliminated. If the rule is modified, what
changes should we make? Should
networks be removed from or added to
the rule? If so, which networks? What
would be the basis for eliminating the
E:\FR\FM\28FEP1.SGM
28FEP1
khammond on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with PROPOSALS
Federal Register / Vol. 84, No. 40 / Thursday, February 28, 2019 / Proposed Rules
rule? If the rule were eliminated, would
antitrust statutes or any other statutes,
rules, or policies serve as a sufficient
backstop to prevent undue
consolidation between or among the Big
Four networks? Why or why not?
59. The Commission also seeks
comment on whether The Dual Network
Rule remains necessary to promote
localism, in particular by maintaining a
balance of power between the Big Four
networks and their local affiliates. To
reach the largest possible national
audience, the Big Four networks acquire
their own broadcast stations, usually in
the largest television markets, and enter
into affiliation agreements with station
owners throughout the rest of the
country. Through affiliation, a model
which has existed for more than fifty
years, networks benefit through wide
delivery of their programming, and
network affiliates benefit by gaining
access to high-quality programming.
The Commission has found in previous
media ownership rule reviews that the
network-affiliate model balances
competing interests: Networks have an
economic incentive to ensure that
programming appeals to a mass,
nationwide audience while affiliates
have an economic incentive to tailor
programming to their local audiences
and influence network programming
choices to ensure that the programming
serves local needs and interests.
Affiliates also may decide individually
to preempt network programming for
other programming better serving the
local audience. The Commission now
seeks comment on whether these
specific conclusions, and the
Commission’s general conclusion that
the Dual Network Rule is needed to
keep the balance of bargaining power
between the Big Four networks and
their affiliates, remain true in today’s
video marketplace.
60. Evidence submitted in the
Commission’s review of the ComcastNBCU merger suggested that broadcast
network affiliation remains sought after
and critical to many local stations’
success. Also, while advertising revenue
remains essential to broadcast stations,
the Eighteenth Video Competition
Report showed that retransmission
consent revenues now represent a much
greater proportion of total revenue for
many broadcast stations than
previously, and stations with Big Four
network affiliations often receive the
lion’s share of retransmission consent
dollars from MVPDs in a local market.
The Eighteenth Video Competition
Report also showed that, whereas local
affiliates were once paid by networks to
distribute network programming, today
networks seek and receive
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:17 Feb 27, 2019
Jkt 247001
compensation from their affiliates in the
form of reverse compensation payments.
According to one estimate by SNL
Kagan, total industrywide reverse
compensation payments paid by
affiliates to broadcast networks have
increased from roughly $300 million in
2010 to $2.9 billion in 2017. There is
some evidence too that networks now
exert leverage through oversight or
approval of affiliate retransmission
consent negotiations, and although not
common, in some instances in recent
years a network dropped or threatened
to drop a local affiliate to launch a
network O&O station in the same
market. To what extent do networks
extract a share of retransmission consent
payments received by their affiliates?
How, if at all, should the Dual Network
Rule account for these or other recent
changes to the network/affiliate
relationship?
61. In addition, the rise of online
video options in recent years also may
have altered the network-affiliate
dynamic. As stated above, OVDs now
reach millions of consumers, creating
new opportunities for networks to
achieve widespread distribution
without the direct involvement of
network affiliates. In the broadcastMVPD world of retransmission consent,
local affiliates may have some recourse
against broadcast networks bypassing
their affiliates in this manner by
negotiating for, and if necessary
enforcing via Commission rules,
contractual network non-duplication
rights, which protect a broadcast
station’s right to be the exclusive
distributor of network programming
within a specified geographic zone. By
contrast, in the world of online video
distribution, local affiliates lack a
comparable regulatory backstop. The
ability of networks to achieve online
distribution of network programming in
a local market, without the need for
local affiliates to consent, may give
networks some additional leverage in
the network-affiliate relationship that
did not exist in the pre-online video
world. What implications, if any, do
developments related to the growth of
online video distribution have for the
Dual Network Rule and its underlying
localism rationale?
62. As the Commission has previously
noted, the Dual Network Rule is
intended to preserve the ability of local
affiliates to advocate for local interests
in programming decisions. Would a Big
Four network merger reduce the ability
of a network affiliate to use the
availability of other top, independentlyowned networks as a bargaining tool to
influence programming decisions of its
network, including the affiliate’s ability
PO 00000
Frm 00047
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
6751
to engage in a dialogue with its network
over the suitability for local audiences
of either the content or scheduling of
network programming? Have changes
discussed above, including the growth
of online video or increased reverse
compensation and retransmission
consent fees, affected bargaining
between networks and affiliates on
programming and scheduling?
63. Considering the longstanding
existence of the Dual Network Rule, has
localism increased, decreased, or
remained roughly the same over time?
Are there recent examples where local
affiliates have influenced network
programming to better serve local
needs? Are there other metrics by which
we can assess the effect of the Dual
Network Rule on localism? Have other
changes affected the network/affiliate
relationship, such that the Commission
would need to adjust assumptions made
in previous reviews of the Dual Network
Rule? For instance, has the growth over
the last two decades of station groups
not owned and operated by networks
changed the dynamic between networks
and their affiliates? Do recent changes
affecting the network-affiliate
relationship suggest that the Dual
Network Rule should be modified,
rather than being retained or eliminated,
to promote localism? If so, what
modifications should we make that
would better promote localism?
64. Minority and Female Ownership.
The Commission concluded in the
2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Order
that, given the Dual Network Rule’s
unique focus on mergers involving the
Big Four networks rather than
ownership limits in local markets, the
rule would not be expected to have any
meaningful impact on minority and
female ownership levels. The
Commission seeks comment on whether
and how market or other changes since
its last media ownership review may
have affected this conclusion. The
Commission also seeks comment on
how retaining, modifying or eliminating
the Dual Network Rule would affect
broadcast television ownership and
entry by minority and female owners, if
at all. Finally, the Commission seeks
comment on how retaining or modifying
the Dual Network Rule might affect
broadcast television ownership and
entry by small business owners, if at all.
65. Diversity Related Proposals. The
NPRM also seeks comment on three
proposals for increasing media diversity
advanced by MMTC in prior
proceedings. These three proposals were
distilled from a larger list based on
guidance from the Third Circuit in its
decisions and Commission staff, and the
Commission already has adopted two
E:\FR\FM\28FEP1.SGM
28FEP1
khammond on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with PROPOSALS
6752
Federal Register / Vol. 84, No. 40 / Thursday, February 28, 2019 / Proposed Rules
additional proposals from this list. The
three proposals the Commission now
considers are: (1) Extending cable
procurement requirements to
broadcasters; (2) developing a model for
market based tradable ‘‘diversity
credits’’ to serve as an alternative
method for adopting ownership limits;
and (3) adopting formulas aimed at
creating media ownership limits that
promote diversity.
66. Extending Cable Procurement
Regulation. The 1992 Cable Act states
that a cable system must: ‘‘[e]ncourage
minority and female entrepreneurs to
conduct business with all parts of its
operation.’’ § 76.75(e) of the
Commission’s rules explains that this
requirement may be met by, for
example, recruiting as wide as possible
a pool of qualified entrepreneurs from
sources such as employee referrals,
community groups, contractors,
associations, and other sources likely to
be representative of minority and female
interests. To help determine whether
this requirement can be applied to
broadcasters, the Commission seeks
comment on the threshold issue of
whether, because Commission cable
procurement authority flows directly
from the 1992 Cable Act, it has authority
to adopt a procurement requirement for
broadcasters. The Communications Act
imposes equal employment opportunity
obligations on broadcasters, but no
procurement requirements. Does this
difference between the two statutes
reflect any limitation on the
Commission’s otherwise extensive
Communications Act Title III authority
over broadcasters? The Commission
seeks comment on potential sources of
Commission authority, including any
ancillary authority, to extend
procurement regulations to the
broadcast industry. The Commission
also seeks comment on whether, by
specifically identifying minority/female
entrepreneurs, the proposal would
classify these entrepreneurs differently
from others such as to trigger
heightened judicial scrutiny. If
heightened scrutiny is triggered, how
would such a rule comport with the
Commission’s previous finding in the
2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Order
that it lacked the evidence to satisfy the
heightened scrutiny needed to justify
race- or gender-based broadcast
regulation? Would inclusion of any type
of audit, review, or enforcement
mechanism pursuant to which the
Commission considered broadcasters’
compliance with the requirement be
problematic or interpreted as tacitly
encouraging broadcasters to favor
certain entrepreneurs to the detriment of
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:17 Feb 27, 2019
Jkt 247001
others in a way that would trigger
heightened scrutiny?
67. If a broadcast procurement rule as
proposed by MMTC would trigger
heightened judicial scrutiny, can any
proposed rule be modified to be raceand gender-neutral to avoid the
potential legal impediments raised by a
race- and gender-conscious broadcast
procurement rule? In such a case, how
would the requirement be stated?
Would a race- and gender-neutral
broadcast procurement rule be as
effective as a race- and gender-conscious
broadcast procurement rule?
68. The Commission also seeks
comment on MMTC’s assertion in the
2010/2014 Quadrennial Review that
§ 76.75(e) ‘‘has been a springboard for
the migration of minority and women
entrepreneurs into operating and
ownership positions in the cable and
satellite industries[,]’’ and has
‘‘contributed mightily to the economic
success of scores of minority and
women owned businesses engaged in
banking, broker/dealer services,
construction, fiber and satellite dish
installation, programming, legal
services, accounting, and much more.’’
In deciding whether to adopt additional
regulations or extend a regulation to
additional industries, it is important to
assess the likelihood that the regulation
would have the desired effect of
increasing minority and female
participation in the broadcast industry.
Consequently, the Commission seeks
data on the degree to which § 76.75(e)
has promoted minority and women
businesses and whether any broader
trends in the intervening two decades
since enactment of the cable
procurement requirement have played a
role in fostering greater minority and
female participation in the cable
industry. In this regard, we also seek
comment on the relative benefits and
costs of extending § 76.75(e) to the
broadcast industry. How can the value
of these benefits and costs be measured?
69. The Commission also notes the
significant differences between the cable
and broadcast industries and seeks
comment on the feasibility—and
utility—of imposing a § 76.75(e)-type
requirement on the broadcast industry.
For example, unlike broadcasters, cable
providers must construct and
continuously maintain and upgrade a
significant physical plant and therefore
purchase goods and services on a much
larger scale than broadcasters. Over-theair delivery of broadcast radio and
television does not require laying fiber
or coaxial cable to every home and, in
most instances, deploying customer
premise equipment, necessitating
regular purchase of equipment and
PO 00000
Frm 00048
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
material at significant volume.
Constructing and maintaining extensive
cable networks also requires employing
and contracting for far more labor than
is required in the broadcast sector.
Unlike broadcasters, cable operators
maintain a direct billing relationship
with their customers, offering more
contracting opportunities—in the form
of outsourced billing or customer
service functions—than the broadcast
industry. Accordingly, the Commission
seeks input on the feasibility and utility
of imposing a cable procurement
regulation on broadcasters.
70. Develop a Model for Market-Based
Tradeable Diversity Credits. In reply
comments submitted in the 2002
Biennial Review, a group called the
Diversity and Competition Supporters
(DCS) advanced several initiatives that
it asserted would foster diversity,
including tradeable ‘‘diversity credits’’
for the broadcast industry. While
diversity credits weren’t well defined,
the idea appears to involve creating a
system of credits tradable in a marketbased system and redeemable by a
broadcaster buying additional stations
to offset any increased concentration
resulting from a proposed transaction.
DCS offered diversity credits as a
potential alternative to the test then in
use by the Commission requiring that,
for a broadcaster to own two stations in
a market, eight independent voices must
have remained in the market posttransaction. DCS suggested that
economists (presumably both at the
Commission and beyond) could explore
the concept and stated its hope ‘‘that
other parties will attempt to design a
market-based Diversity Credit program.’’
In 2004, a member of the Transactional
Transparency Subcommittee of the FCC
Advisory Committee on Diversity in the
Digital Age further developed the
diversity credits concept, suggesting
credits linked to each broadcast license
based on the extent to which the
licensee was ‘‘socially and economically
disadvantaged’’ and that, if a transaction
promoted diversity (e.g., the breakup of
a local ownership cluster or the sale of
a station to a socially and economically
disadvantaged business), the
Commission would award the seller
additional diversity credits
‘‘commensurate with the extent to
which the transaction promotes
diversity.’’ Similarly, according to this
2004 proposal, if a transaction reduced
diversity (e.g., by creating an ownership
combination or growing an ownership
cluster), the Commission would require
diversity credits from the buyer,
commensurate with the extent to the
which the transaction reduced diversity.
E:\FR\FM\28FEP1.SGM
28FEP1
khammond on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with PROPOSALS
Federal Register / Vol. 84, No. 40 / Thursday, February 28, 2019 / Proposed Rules
Finally, according to the 2004 proposal,
if a company seeking approval of a
transaction held insufficient diversity
credits to gain approval, the company
would need to purchase diversity
credits on a secondary market from
third-party companies. The proposal did
not define either ‘‘promoting’’ or
‘‘reducing’’ diversity, or how the impact
of a transaction would be measured or
quantified. MMTC continued to
advocate for tradable diversity credits in
the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review,
asking the Commission to explore their
feasibility by issuing a Notice of Inquiry.
Therefore, the Commission now seeks
comment on whether and how it should
create a system of tradable diversity
credits that would foster ownership
diversity in broadcasting.
71. The Commission first seeks
comment on its authority to adopt a
tradeable diversity credit system within
its structural broadcast ownership rules
or otherwise. While the
Communications Act contains no
explicit authority to create or rely on
such a program, when presenting the
idea, DCS asserted that the sections
303(f), (g), and (r) of the
Communications Act provided authority
to implement tradable diversity credits.
Are the sections cited by DCS applicable
to such credits?
72. Assuming it has the required
authority, the Commission seeks
comment on the feasibility of relying on
determinations about social and
economic disadvantage given its
concerns, expressed in the 2010/2014
Quadrennial Review Order, about
relying on such determinations. As
proposed, the allocation of diversity
credits was based on the extent to which
the licensee could be considered
‘‘socially and economically
disadvantaged.’’ How should the term
‘‘socially and economically
disadvantaged’’ business (SDB) be
defined? The 2004 proposal stated that,
‘‘[m]inority status could be a factor in
qualifying as an SDB if the Commission
finds through rulemaking that
minorities, under certain conditions, are
socially and economically
disadvantaged in the broadcasting
industry because of their race[,]’’ but did
not provide any guidance about when
an individual might or might not qualify
on the basis of race. In the 2010/2014
Quadrennial Review Order, the
Commission found that the record did
not establish a basis for race-conscious
remedies and concluded that such
measures were unlikely to withstand
review under the equal protection
component of the Constitution’s due
process clause. Thus, the Commission,
unlike the Small Business
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:17 Feb 27, 2019
Jkt 247001
Administration (SBA), declined to adopt
an SDB eligibility standard that would
have recognized the race and ethnicity
of applicants, or any other race- or
gender-conscious measure. Given the
Commission’s previous findings and
conclusions, can it adopt a diversity
credit program that considers race or
gender, or other protected classes, in a
manner that could withstand equal
protection review? Commenters
advocating for such a program should
explain in detail, based on relevant
judicial precedent and existing
empirical data, how circumstances have
changed such that the Commission
could now overcome the significant
evidentiary issues that it previously
found would need to be resolved to
adopt race- or gender-based policies that
could withstand heightened judicial
scrutiny.
73. If the socially and economically
disadvantaged concept in the 2004
proposal was a precursor to the
Overcoming Disadvantages Preference
(ODP) concept that MMTC has
advanced in subsequent Commission
rulemaking proceedings, the
Commission in the 2010/2014
Quadrennial Review FNPRM assessed
the ODP concept and stated concerns
that the Commission lacks the resources
needed to conduct the individualized
reviews central to ODP. The
Commission has similar concerns about
the administrative and practical
challenges of developing, implementing
and applying a diversity credits
program. The 2004 proposal suggested
that the program rely on ascribing a
diversity credits number to each
broadcast license or possibly each
licensee. Who would make that
allocation of diversity credits, and on
what criteria would the Commission or
other arbiter determine the number of
credits to be awarded to each license or
licensee?
74. Such a program also raises
potentially complicated definitional
issues. How would the Commission
define ‘‘diversity’’ in this context? In the
2002 Biennial Review Order, the
Commission described several types of
diversity, focusing on viewpoint
diversity as the relevant touchstone for
purposes of the structural media
ownership rules. Would a diversity
credit system have as its goal fostering
viewpoint diversity, ownership
diversity, both forms of diversity, or
some other type of diversity?
75. Once diversity is defined, how
would parties—or the Commission—
determine, qualitatively or
quantitatively, whether a transaction
promotes or harms diversity? How
would the degree to which the
PO 00000
Frm 00049
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
6753
transaction harms or benefits diversity
be quantified, such that the number of
credits awarded for, or required before
approval of, such a transaction could be
determined? For example, would the
impact on diversity vary depending on
the size of the market, the number of
operators therein, or the characteristics
of the stations involved in the
transaction? Would a requirement that
parties remit to the Commission a
certain number of diversity credits to
receive approval of a transaction replace
the Commission’s existing structural
broadcast ownership rules, which are
based primarily on other policy goals,
such as competition and localism? Or
would compliance with the diversity
credit regime be an additional
requirement before a transaction were
permitted?
76. Recognizing that diversity credits
could be used as a form of currency in
the broadcast market, how could the
Commission effectively test such a
scheme to ensure it would not lead to
any unintended consequences?
Developing and implementing a system
that ensures that the award of diversity
credits leads to the desired result—
increasing diverse ownership in the
broadcast market—rather than
inadvertently skewing the market
towards an unintended outcome,
including greater concentration or loss
of localism and viewpoint diversity,
would seem to be a particular challenge.
The Commission seeks comment on
how to address these issues.
77. Tipping Point Formula and Source
Diversity Formula. In 2002, MMTC
proposed a ‘‘tipping point formula’’ for
use in the local radio market in lieu of
the Commission’s now-abandoned
practice of ‘‘flagging’’ radio transactions
that, after initial analysis based on
advertising revenue, approached a level
of local concentration that raised public
interest concerns about preserving
diversity and competition. In 2003, DCS
proposed a ‘‘source diversity formula’’
for use in the broader media market that
seemed to be an attempt to quantify the
benefit derived from increased
viewpoint diversity. As with diversity
credits, the Communications Act
provides no explicit authority to adopt
or apply these formulas, and the
Commission seeks comment on possible
sources of such statutory authority.
Moreover, because MMTC and DCS
have provided little update to the
formulas since proposing them, the
Commission seeks input generally on
their relevance in today’s marketplace.
The formulas also raise administrative
and practical concerns on which the
Commission seeks comment, as
discussed below.
E:\FR\FM\28FEP1.SGM
28FEP1
Federal Register / Vol. 84, No. 40 / Thursday, February 28, 2019 / Proposed Rules
khammond on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with PROPOSALS
LSTP: Local Service Tipping Point, i.e., the
point at which, if the top two station groups
control more revenue, independents will
begin to lose their ability to offer meaningful
local service.
SUTP: Survival Tipping Point, i.e., the
point at which, if the top two station groups
control more revenue, independents will be
unable to meet their fixed operating costs and
must, therefore, sell out or go dark.
MR: Market revenue.
MR1: Amount of market revenue drawn by
largest platform.
MR2: Amount of market revenue drawn by
second largest platform.
IN: Number of independent stations in the
market.
SU: Minimum fixed cost for an
independent station to stay on the air.
VFSU: Variability Factor for Survival
Operations, reflecting the average amount of
revenues per independent station that must
be available in the market, collectively, to
take account of variations among the
independent stations and thereby ensure that
well-run weak independents stay on the air.
LS: Minimum additional cost, beyond SU,
for an independent station to offer a
meaningful local service.
VFLS: Variability Factor for Local Service
reflecting the average amount of revenue per
independent station that must be available in
the market, collectively, to take account of
variations among the independent stations
and thereby ensure that well-run weak
independents remain viable.
Based on these inputs, according to
MMTC, the Local Service Tipping Point
is the point at which: IN (SU + VFSU
+ LS + VFLS) = MR¥(MR1 + MR2), and
the Survival Tipping point is the point
at which: IN (SU + VFSU) = MR¥(MR1
+ MR2). In presenting these variables,
MMTC noted that ‘‘[t]he cost of
maintaining a station on the air varies
somewhat depending on local market
factors[,]’’ that such regional or local
differences ‘‘can be designed into a
formula by indexing a market’s cost of
living relative to the national average[,]’’
and that such issues could be addressed
in a negotiated rulemaking involving all
interested parties.
79. We seek comment on the various
terms used in the formula. For example,
how should the terms ‘‘independent’’
and ‘‘platform’’ be defined in the
context of today’s radio marketplace?
How should the terms ‘‘well-run
independent’’ and ‘‘well-run weak
independent’’ be defined? What
objective criteria can we apply to
distinguish between a ‘‘well-run
independent’’ and a ‘‘well-run weak
independent’’ to ensure that use of a
tipping point formula does not prop up
stations that are either poorly managed
or simply not airing programming that
responds to the community’s interests?
What is meant by ‘‘meaningful local
service’’? We also seek comment on
whether any determinations about how
well a station is run or the concept of
‘‘meaningful local service’’ might create
First Amendment concerns.
80. MMTC’s formula appears to rely
on advertising revenues. If so, how
would the Commission and potential
applicants obtain reliable advertising
revenue for all radio stations? If another
type of revenue is more appropriate,
what data would the Commission rely
on to obtain information about this
other revenue? How should the concept
of ‘‘fixed operating costs’’ be quantified?
How should the Commission account
for local and regional cost differences?
81. Finally, the Commission seeks
comment on what seems to be the
fundamental premise behind MMTC’s
tipping point formula: that retaining
independents (however that term is
defined) in a market maintains diversity
(however that term is defined). We also
invite commenters to address any other
issues that they believe are raised by the
tipping point formula proposal.
82. DCS submitted its source diversity
formula in response to a challenge from
then-Chairman Powell to derive an
‘‘HHI [Herfindahl-Hirschman Index
used to measure market concentration]
for Diversity.’’ The formula appears to
seek to measure the level of consumer
welfare derived from viewpoint
diversity in the radio and television
broadcast market, and DCS suggested it
could be a ‘‘thermometer’’ to determine
whether ‘‘a national or local market
manifest[s] strong diversity, moderate
diversity, or slight diversity.’’ DCS
proposed that the Commission conduct
a negotiated rulemaking to determine
what significance to accord to various
‘‘temperature readings’’ on this
thermometer, i.e., what temperatures
would reflect ‘‘poor health,’’ or ‘‘strong
health.’’ DCS appeared to suggest that
the source diversity formula could be
used in lieu of the Commission’s nowrepealed ‘‘eight voices’’ test.
83. DCS depicted the source diversity
formula as shown below with the
following variables: X = consumer
welfare derived from viewpoint
diversity; p = a program consumed from
a particular source; g = the number of
programs from a particular source that
are available for consumption; C = the
number of consumers consuming a
particular program; T = consumers’
mean media consumption time devoted
to the absorption of viewpoints in a
particular program; Z = consumers’
mean attentiveness to a particular
program; m = a source (including all
outlets owned by that source); and n =
number of differently owned sources
offering programs consumed. The
formula as proposed was:
DCS acknowledged that the formula was
imperfect and would need testing and
validation before deployment.
84. The formula raises several
fundamental questions. Is the formula
sufficiently comprehensive for
commenters to gauge without additional
explanation whether it can provide a
meaningful assessment of consumer
welfare and viewpoint diversity in a
particular market? Are there terms used
in the formula inputs that require
definition prior to any assessment of the
formula’s utility? For example, do terms
such as ‘‘source’’ and ‘‘program’’ need to
78. MMTC’s tipping point formula
attempted to determine when a
proposed transaction would create an
entity that could control so much
advertising revenue that ‘‘well run
independents’’ could not survive or
offer ‘‘meaningful local service’’ (all
undefined). The formula’s asserted goal
was to assess how much ‘‘revenue’’ an
‘‘independent’’ would need on average
to survive in a given market, with this
number then being multiplied by the
number of ‘‘independents’’ in that
market. Because the Commission’s
abandoned flagging approach relied on
advertising revenues, the term
‘‘revenue’’ in MMTC’s tipping point
formula appears also to refer to
advertising revenue. MMTC essentially
suggests that the Commission should
bar any transaction that would reduce
the revenue available to support
independent operators in a market to an
amount below what could sustain those
operators. Stated differently, a
broadcaster would not be permitted to
acquire competing stations in a market
if the purchase would create revenue so
great as to leave insufficient revenue for
the independents in the market. MMTC
provided the following variables as
inputs for its formula, as well as the
formula shown below:
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:17 Feb 27, 2019
Jkt 247001
PO 00000
Frm 00050
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
E:\FR\FM\28FEP1.SGM
28FEP1
EP28FE19.006
6754
khammond on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with PROPOSALS
Federal Register / Vol. 84, No. 40 / Thursday, February 28, 2019 / Proposed Rules
be defined before analyzing the
formula? Are there other terms that need
defining? How will the formula inputs
be obtained? For example, we seek
comment on how to capture inputs such
as ‘‘consumers’ mean attentiveness to a
particular program’’ and ‘‘consumers’
mean media consumption time devoted
to the absorption of viewpoints in a
particular program.’’ How should the
Commission determine the level of
diversity to ascribe to various formula
results (e.g., ‘‘strong diversity,’’
‘‘moderate diversity,’’ or ‘‘slight
diversity’’)? Finally, the Commission
invites commenters to address any other
issues that they believe are raised by the
source diversity formula.
85. Cost-Benefit Analysis. For the
three structural media ownership rules
and all of the diversity-related proposals
discussed above, the Commission seeks
comment on how to compare the
benefits and costs associated with
retaining, modifying or eliminating the
rule or adopting the diversity-related
proposal, with any proposed
modification to the proposal.
Commenters supporting modification or
elimination of any rule or adoption of
any proposal should explain the
anticipated economic impact of any
proposed action and, where possible,
quantify benefits and costs of proposed
actions and alternatives. Do the current
rules create benefits or costs for any
segment of consumers? Do the rules
create benefits or costs for any segment
of the industry that should be counted
as social benefits or costs rather than
transfers from one segment of the
industry to another? How do the rules
create these benefits and costs, and what
evidence supports this explanation?
How can the value of these benefits and
costs be measured for parties receiving
them? What factors create uncertainty
about the existence or size of these
benefits and costs, and how should the
Commission’s economic analysis take
these uncertainties into account?
86. How would elimination of any
rules alter the benefits and costs? What
are the comparative benefits and costs of
modifying any rule rather than
eliminating it entirely? For instance,
would loosening the current local
television or local radio ownership
restrictions, or allowing certain of the
Big Four networks and not others to
merge lead to any consumer benefits,
such as increased choice, innovation, or
investment in programming? What
amount of additional scale would be
required to realize such benefits? Would
these benefits conflict with, or come at
a cost to, our traditional policy goals of
competition, viewpoint diversity or
localism, and if so, how should we
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:17 Feb 27, 2019
Jkt 247001
measure and evaluate these tradeoffs?
What are the comparative benefits and
costs of tightening the current
restrictions? The Commission asks
commenters to support their claims
about benefits and costs with relevant
economic theory and evidence,
including empirical analysis and data.
Procedural Matters
87. Ex Parte Rules—Permit-ButDisclose. The proceeding that this
NPRM initiates shall be treated as a
‘‘permit-but-disclose’’ proceeding in
accordance with the Commission’s ex
parte rules. Persons making ex parte
presentations must file a copy of any
written presentation or a memorandum
summarizing any oral presentation
within two business days after the
presentation (unless a different deadline
applicable to the Sunshine period
applies). Persons making oral ex parte
presentations are reminded that
memoranda summarizing the
presentation must: (1) List all persons
attending or otherwise participating in
the meeting at which the ex parte
presentation was made; and (2)
summarize all data presented and
arguments made during the
presentation. If the presentation
consisted in whole or in part of the
presentation of data or arguments
already reflected in the presenter’s
written comments, memoranda or other
filings in the proceeding, the presenter
may provide citations to such data or
arguments in his or her prior comments,
memoranda, or other filings (specifying
the relevant page and/or paragraph
numbers where such data or arguments
can be found) in lieu of summarizing
them in the memorandum. Documents
shown or given to Commission staff
during ex parte meetings are deemed to
be written ex parte presentations and
must be filed consistent with § 1.1206(b)
of the Commission’s rules. In
proceedings governed by § 1.49(f) of the
Commission’s rules, or for which the
Commission has made available a
method of electronic filing, written ex
parte presentations and memoranda
summarizing oral ex parte
presentations, and all attachments
thereto, must be filed through the
Commission’s Electronic Comment
Filing System (ECFS) available for that
proceeding, and must be filed in their
native format (e.g., .doc, .xml, .ppt,
searchable .pdf). Participants in this
proceeding should familiarize
themselves with the Commission’s ex
parte rules.
88. Filing Requirements—Comments
and Replies. Pursuant to §§ 1.415 and
1.419 of the Commission’s rules,
interested parties may file comments
PO 00000
Frm 00051
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
6755
and reply comments on or before the
dates indicated on the first page of this
document. Comments may be filed
using ECFS.
• Electronic Filers: Comments may be
filed electronically using the internet by
accessing the ECFS: https://apps.fcc.gov/
ecfs/.
• Paper Filers: Parties who choose to
file by paper must file an original and
one copy of each filing.
Filings can be sent by hand or
messenger delivery, by commercial
overnight courier, or by first-class or
overnight U.S. Postal Service mail. All
filings must be addressed to the
Commission’s Secretary, Office of the
Secretary, Federal Communications
Commission.
• All hand-delivered or messengerdelivered paper filings for the
Commission’s Secretary must be
delivered to FCC Headquarters at 445
12th St. SW, Room TW–A325,
Washington, DC 20554. The filing hours
are 8:00 a.m. to 7:00 p.m. All hand
deliveries must be held together with
rubber bands or fasteners. Any
envelopes and boxes must be disposed
of before entering the building.
• Commercial overnight mail (other
than U.S. Postal Service Express Mail
and Priority Mail) must be sent to 9050
Junction Drive, Annapolis Junction, MD
20701.
• U.S. Postal Service first-class,
Express, and Priority mail must be
addressed to 445 12th Street SW,
Washington, DC 20554.
89. Initial Regulatory Flexibility Act
Analysis. The Regulatory Flexibility Act
of 1980, as amended (RFA), requires
that a regulatory flexibility analysis be
prepared for notice and comment
rulemaking proceedings, unless the
agency certifies that ‘‘the rule will not,
if promulgated, have a significant
economic impact on a substantial
number of small entities.’’ The RFA
generally defines the term ‘‘small
entity’’ as having the same meaning as
the terms ‘‘small business,’’ ‘‘small
organization,’’ and ‘‘small governmental
jurisdiction.’’ In addition, the term
‘‘small business’’ has the same meaning
as the term ‘‘small business concern’’
under the Small Business Act. A ‘‘small
business concern’’ is one which: (1) Is
independently owned and operated; (2)
is not dominant in its field of operation;
and (3) satisfies any additional criteria
established by the Small Business
Administration (SBA).
90. Written public comments are
requested on the IFRA and must be filed
in accordance with the same filing
deadlines as comments on this NPRM,
with a distinct heading designating
them as responses to the IRFA. In
E:\FR\FM\28FEP1.SGM
28FEP1
6756
Federal Register / Vol. 84, No. 40 / Thursday, February 28, 2019 / Proposed Rules
khammond on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with PROPOSALS
addition, a copy of this NPRM and the
IRFA will be sent to the Chief Counsel
for Advocacy of the SBA.
91. Paperwork Reduction Act. This
NPRM seeks comment on whether the
Commission should adopt new or
modified information collection
requirements. The Commission, as part
of its continuing effort to reduce
paperwork burdens and pursuant to the
Paperwork Reduction Act of 1995,
invites the public and the Office of
Management and Budget (OMB) to
comment on these information
collection requirements. In addition,
pursuant to the Small Business
Paperwork Relief Act of 2002, we seek
specific comment on how we might
further reduce the information
collection burden for small business
concerns with fewer than 25 employees.
92. People with Disabilities. To
request materials in accessible formats
for people with disabilities (braille,
large print, electronic files, audio
format), send an email to fcc504@fcc.gov
or call the Consumer and Governmental
Affairs Bureau at 202–418–0530 (voice),
202–418–0432 (tty).
93. Additional Information. For
additional information on this
proceeding, please contact Brendan
Holland of the Media Bureau, Industry
Analysis Division, Brendan.Holland@
fcc.gov, (202) 418–2757.
Initial Regulatory Flexibility Analysis
94. Need for, and Objective of, the
Proposed Rules. This NPRM begins an
examination of the Commission’s media
ownership rules and possible changes to
these rules. As discussed in the NPRM,
the Commission is required by statute to
review its media ownership rules every
four years to determine whether they
‘‘are necessary in the public interest as
the result of competition.’’ Consistent
with the Communications Act, the
Commission must examine its media
ownership rules and consider whether
they continue to serve our public
interest goals of competition, viewpoint
diversity and localism, or whether they
should be modified or eliminated.
Specifically, the NPRM examines the
three remaining media ownership rules,
the Local Radio Ownership Rule, the
Local Television Ownership Rule and
the Dual Network Rule. In addition, the
NPRM seeks comment on several
proposals that were advanced in
previous rulemakings and which the
Commission indicated it would examine
further in the context of this review of
its structural ownership rules. These
proposals, to extend cable procurement
requirements to broadcasters, develop a
model for market-based, tradeable
‘‘diversity credits’’ to serve as an
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:17 Feb 27, 2019
Jkt 247001
alternative method for adopting
ownership limits, and adopt formulas
aimed at creating media ownership
limits that promote diversity, are
presented by their proponents as
initiatives that could further the
Commission’s diversity goal. The
Commission anticipates that these
initiatives, if ultimately adopted, might
benefit small entities.
95. Legal Basis. The proposed action
is authorized under sections 1, 2(a), 4(i),
303, 307, 309, and 310 of the
Communications Act of 1934, as
amended, and section 202(h) of the
Telecommunications Act of 1996.
96. Description and Estimate of the
Number of Small Entities to which the
Proposed Rules Apply. The RFA directs
agencies to provide a description of, and
where feasible, an estimate of the
number of small entities that may be
affected by the proposed rule revisions,
if adopted. The RFA generally defines
the term ‘‘small entity’’ as having the
same meaning as the terms ‘‘small
business,’’ ‘‘small organization,’’ and
‘‘small governmental jurisdiction.’’ In
addition, the term ‘‘small business’’ has
the same meaning as the term ‘‘small
business concern’’ under the Small
Business Act (SBA). A small business
concern is one which: (1) Is
independently owned and operated; (2)
is not dominant in its field of operation;
and (3) satisfies any additional criteria
established by the SBA. Below, we
provide a description of such small
entities, as well as an estimate of the
number of such small entities, where
feasible.
97. Television Broadcasting.
According to the U.S. Census Bureau
2017 NAICS Definitions, this U.S.
Economic Census category ‘‘comprises
establishments primarily engaged in
broadcasting images together with
sound.’’ These establishments operate
television broadcast studios and
facilities for the programming and
transmission of programs to the public.
These establishments also produce or
transmit visual programming to
affiliated broadcast television stations,
which in turn broadcast the programs to
the public on a predetermined schedule.
Programming may originate in their own
studio, from an affiliated network, or
from external sources. The SBA has
created the following small business
size standard for such businesses: those
having $38.5 million or less in annual
receipts. The 2012 Economic Census
reports that 751 firms in this category
operated in that year. Of that number,
656 had annual receipts of $25 million
or less, 25 had annual receipts between
$25 million and $49,999,999 and 70 had
annual receipts of $50 million or more.
PO 00000
Frm 00052
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
Based on this data, the Commission
estimates that the majority of
commercial television broadcast stations
are small entities under the applicable
size standard.
98. Additionally, the Commission has
estimated the number of licensed
commercial television stations to be
1,349. Of this total, 1,248 stations (or
about 92.5 percent) had revenues of
$38.5 million or less, according to
Commission staff review of the BIA
Kelsey Inc. Media Access Pro Television
Database (BIA) in November 2018, and
therefore these stations qualify as small
entities under the SBA definition.
99. Radio Broadcasting. This U.S.
Economic Census category ‘‘comprises
establishments primarily engaged in
broadcasting aural programs by radio to
the public.’’ Programming may originate
in their own studio, from an affiliated
network, or from external sources. The
SBA has created the following small
business size standard for such
businesses: those having $38.5 million
or less in annual receipts. Economic
Census data for 2012 show that 2,849
firms in this category operated in that
year. Of that number, 2,806 operated
with annual receipts of less than $25
million per year, 17 with annual
receipts between $25 million and
$49,999,999 and 26 with annual receipts
of $50 million or more. Based on this
data, we estimate that the majority of
commercial radio broadcast stations
were small under the applicable SBA
size standard.
100. Apart from the U.S. Economic
Census, the Commission has estimated
the number of licensed commercial AM
radio stations to be 4,426 stations and
the number of commercial FM radio
stations to be 6,737, for a total number
of 11,364. Of this total, 11,355 stations
(or 99.9 percent) had revenues of $38.5
million or less, according to
Commission staff review of the BIA
Kelsey Inc. Media Access Pro Television
Database (BIA) in November 2018, and
therefore these stations qualify as small
entities under the SBA definition.
101. In assessing whether a business
concern qualifies as small under the
above definition, business (control)
affiliations must be included. Our
estimate, therefore, likely overstates the
number of small entities that might be
affected by our action because the
revenue figure on which it is based does
not include or aggregate revenues from
affiliated companies. In addition, an
element of the definition of ‘‘small
business’’ is that the entity not be
dominant in its field of operation. We
are unable at this time to define or
quantify the criteria that would
establish whether a specific radio or
E:\FR\FM\28FEP1.SGM
28FEP1
khammond on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with PROPOSALS
Federal Register / Vol. 84, No. 40 / Thursday, February 28, 2019 / Proposed Rules
television station is dominant in its field
of operation. Accordingly, the estimate
of small businesses to which the
proposed rules may apply does not
exclude any radio or television station
from the definition of small business on
this basis and is therefore possibly overinclusive.
102. Description of Projected
Reporting, Recordkeeping and other
Compliance Requirements. The
proposals, if ultimately adopted, would
require modification of several
Commission forms and their
instructions: (1) FCC Form 301,
Application for Construction Permit for
Commercial Broadcast Station; (2) FCC
Form 314, Application for Consent to
Assignment of Broadcast Station
Construction Permit or License; and (3)
FCC Form 315, Application for Consent
to Transfer Control of Corporation
Holding Broadcast Station Construction
Permit or License. The Commission also
would modify, as necessary, other forms
that include in their instructions the
media ownership rules or citations to
media ownership proceedings,
including Form 303–S, Application for
Renewal License for AM, FM, TV,
Translator, or LPTV Station and Form
323, Ownership Report for Commercial
Broadcast Station. The impact of these
changes will be the same on all entities,
and we do not anticipate that
compliance will require the expenditure
of any additional resources or place
additional burdens on small businesses.
103. Steps Taken to Minimize
Significant Economic Impact on Small
Entities, and Significant—Alternatives
Considered. The RFA requires an
agency to describe any significant
alternatives that it has considered in
reaching its proposed approach, which
may include the following four
alternatives (among others): (1) The
establishment of differing compliance or
reporting requirements or timetables
that take into account the resources
available to small entities; (2) the
clarification, consolidation, or
simplification of compliance or
reporting requirements under the rule
for small entities; (3) the use of
performance, rather than design,
standards; and (4) an exemption from
coverage of the rule, or any part thereof,
for small entities.
104. The NPRM begins a statutorily
mandated examination of whether three
remaining media ownership rules
remain in the public interest as a result
of competition and promote the
Commission’s longstanding policy goals
of competition, viewpoint diversity and
localism. The NPRM acknowledges new
technologies and changed marketplace
conditions that affect whether the rules
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:17 Feb 27, 2019
Jkt 247001
remain in the public interest
considering competition and the need to
allow broadcasters, including small
entities, to achieve the economies of
scale and scope necessary to continue to
compete in a changed marketplace. The
NPRM considers measures designed to
minimize the economic impact of any
changes to these rules on firms
generally, as well as initiatives designed
to promote broadcast ownership
opportunities among a diverse group of
owners, including small entities. The
NPRM also invites comment on the
effects of any rule changes on different
types of broadcasters (e.g., independent
or network-affiliated), the benefits and
costs associated with any proposals, and
any potential to have significant impact
on small entities.
105. The NPRM proposes no new
reporting requirements, performance
standards or other compliance
obligations, although, as discussed
above, it may modify, as necessary,
certain existing reporting forms should
it adopt any changes to its media
ownership rules. Should the
Commission ultimately adopt changes
to its media ownership rules that could
increase requirements or compliance
burdens for small entities, it will
determine whether possible exemptions,
waiver opportunities, extended
compliance deadlines or other measures
would mitigate any potential impact on
small entities.
106. Federal Rules that May
Duplicate, Overlap or Conflict with the
Proposed Rules. None.
Ordering Clauses
107. Accordingly, it is ordered that,
pursuant to the authority contained in
sections 1, 2(a), 4(i), 257, 303, 307, 309,
310, and 403 of the Communications
Act of 1934, as amended, and section
202(h) of the Telecommunications Act
of 1996, this Notice of Proposed
Rulemaking is adopted.
108. It is further ordered, pursuant to
applicable procedures set forth in
§§ 1.415 and 1.419 of the Commission’s
rules, interested parties may file
comments on the NPRM in MB Docket
No. 18–349 on or before sixty (60) days
after publication in the Federal Register
and reply comments on or before ninety
(90) days after publication in the
Federal Register.
109. It is furthered ordered that the
Commission’s Consumer and
Governmental Affairs Bureau, Reference
Information Center, shall send a copy of
this NPRM, including the IRFA, to the
Chief Counsel for Advocacy of the Small
Business Administration.
PO 00000
Frm 00053
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
6757
Federal Communications Commission.
Katura Jackson,
Federal Register Liaison Officer, Office of the
Secretary.
[FR Doc. 2019–03278 Filed 2–27–19; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6712–01–P
FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS
COMMISSION
47 CFR Part 73
[MB Docket No. 19–18; RM–11823; DA 19–
44]
Television Broadcasting Services
Gadsden and Hoover, Alabama
Federal Communications
Commission.
ACTION: Proposed rule.
AGENCY:
At the request of ION Media
License Company, LLC. (ION), licensee
of television station WPXH-TV, channel
45, Gadsden, Alabama (WPXH), the
Commission is proposing to amend the
DTV Table of Allotments by changing
WPXH’s community of license from
Gadsden to Hoover, Alabama. ION
asserts that the proposed reallotment is
consistent with the Commission’s
second allotment priority by providing
Hoover with its first local transmission
service. ION also asserts that the
proposed reallotment will not deprive
Gadsden of its sole broadcast station
because it will continue to be served by
station WPXH-TV, licensed to Trinity
Christian Center of Santa Ana, Inc. on
channel 26 at Gadsden.
DATES: Comments must be filed on or
before March 15, 2019 and reply
comments on or before March 25, 2019.
ADDRESSES: Federal Communications
Commission, Office of the Secretary,
445 12th Street SW, Washington, DC
20554. In addition to filing comments
with the FCC, interested parties should
serve counsel for petitioner as follows:
ION Media License Company, LLC, c/o
Terri McGalliard, 601 Clearwater Park
Road, West Palm Beach, Florida 33401.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
Darren Fernandez, Media Bureau, at
Darren.Fernandez@fcc.gov; or Joyce
Bernstein, Media Bureau, at
Joyce.Bernstein@fcc.gov.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: This is a
synopsis of the Commission’s Notice of
Proposed Rulemaking, MB Docket No.
19–18; RM–11823; DA 19–43, adopted
February 5, 2019, and released February
5, 2019. In addition to the proposed
reallotment, ION requests waivers of
§ 73.625(a)(1) of the Commission’s rules,
47 CFR 73.625(a)(1) and the
Commission’s freeze on the filing of
SUMMARY:
E:\FR\FM\28FEP1.SGM
28FEP1
Agencies
[Federal Register Volume 84, Number 40 (Thursday, February 28, 2019)]
[Proposed Rules]
[Pages 6741-6757]
From the Federal Register Online via the Government Publishing Office [www.gpo.gov]
[FR Doc No: 2019-03278]
=======================================================================
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION
47 CFR Part 73
[MB Docket No. 18-349; FCC 18-179]
2018 Quadrennial Regulatory Review--Review of the Commission's
Broadcast Ownership Rules
AGENCY: Federal Communications Commission.
ACTION: Proposed rule.
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
SUMMARY: In this document, the Commission's Notice of Proposed
Rulemaking (NPRM) initiates the 2018 quadrennial review of its media
ownership rules, launched pursuant to a requirement of the
Telecommunications Act of 1996 (1996 Act) that the Commission review
its media ownership rules every four years to determine whether they
remain ``necessary in the public interest as the result of
competition'' and to ``repeal or modify any determine[d] to be no
longer in the public interest.'' The three rules currently subject to
review are the Local Radio Ownership Rule, the Local Television
Ownership Rule, and the Dual Network Rule. The NPRM seeks comment on
whether, given the current state of the media marketplace, the
Commission should retain, modify, or eliminate any of these rules. The
NPRM also seeks comment on several proposals offered as potential pro-
diversity initiatives.
DATES: Comments due April 29, 2019. Reply comments due May 29, 2019.
ADDRESSES: Interested parties may submit comments and replies,
identified by MB Docket No. 18-349, by any of the following methods:
Federal eRulemaking Portal: https://www.regulations.gov.
Follow the instructions for submitting comments.
Federal Communications Commission's website: https://www.fcc.gov/cgb/ecfs/. Follow the instructions for submitting comments.
Mail: Filings can be sent by hand or messenger delivery,
by commercial overnight courier, or by first-class or overnight U.S.
Postal Service mail (although the Commission continues to experience
delays in receiving U.S. Postal Service mail). All filings must be
addressed to the Commission's Secretary, Office of the Secretary,
Federal Communications Commission.
For more detailed filing instructions, see the Procedural Matters
section below.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: Brendan Holland, Industry Analysis
Division, Media Bureau, Brendan.Holland@fcc.gov (202) 418-2757.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: This is a summary of the Commission's Notice
of Proposed Rulemaking (NPRM) in MB Docket No. 18-349; FCC 18-179,
adopted on December 12, 2018, and released on December 13, 2018. The
full text of this document is available for public inspection during
regular business hours in the FCC Reference Center, 445 12th Street SW,
Room CY-A257, Washington, DC 20554, or online at https://docs.fcc.gov/public/attachments/FCC-18-179A1.pdf. To request this document in
accessible formats for people with disabilities (e.g., braille, large
print, electronic files, audio format, etc.) or to request reasonable
accommodations (e.g., accessible format documents, sign language
interpreters, CART, etc.), send an email to fcc504@fcc.gov or call the
FCC's Consumer and Governmental Affairs Bureau at (202) 418-0530
(voice), (202) 418-0432 (TTY).
Synopsis
1. Background. Last year, the Commission completed its prior
combined 2010/2014 review of its media ownership rules by adopting an
Order on Reconsideration (2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Order on
Reconsideration) of its initial Order (2010/2014 Quadrennial Review
Order), a reconsideration that relaxed or eliminated several rules,
including repeal of the previous bans on newspaper/broadcast and radio/
television cross-ownership in a market. In the 2010/2014 Quadrennial
Review Order on Reconsideration the Commission revised the Local
Television Ownership Rule by eliminating the requirement that, in order
to own two stations in a market, eight independent voices must remain
in the market post-transaction, and concluded that it would consider,
on a case-by-case basis, combinations that would otherwise be barred by
the prohibition on ownership of two top-four ranked stations in a
market. In eliminating and revising its rules, the Commission
recognized the dynamic changes in the media marketplace and the wealth
of information sources now available to consumers. The Commission also
found that, while the record in the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review
supported adoption of an incubator program to foster the entry of new
and diverse voices in the broadcasting industry, the structure and
implementation of such a program required further exploration.
Accordingly, the Commission sought comment on these issues, and on
August 2, 2018, adopted a Report and Order (Incubator Order)
establishing an incubator program to foster new entry into the
broadcasting industry. Under the program, an established broadcaster
(i.e., incubating entity) will provide a new entrant or small
broadcaster (i.e., incubated entity) with training, financing, and
access to resources that would be otherwise inaccessible to these
entities. In return for this support, the incubating entity can receive
a waiver of the applicable Local Radio Ownership Rule that it can use
either in the incubated market or in a comparable market within three
years of the successful conclusion of a qualifying incubation
relationship.
2. Multiple parties sought reconsideration and judicial review of
the Commission's 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Order, 2010/2014
Quadrennial Review Order on Reconsideration and Incubator Order. The
Third Circuit U.S. Court of Appeals has consolidated the petitions for
judicial review of these Orders and its review is pending.
3. Local Radio Ownership Rule. The rule allows an entity to own:
(1) Up to eight commercial radio stations in radio markets with at
least 45 radio stations, no more than five of which may be in the same
service (AM or FM); (2) up to seven commercial radio stations in radio
markets with 30-44 radio stations, no more than four of which may be in
the same service (AM or FM); (3) up to six commercial radio stations in
radio markets with 15-29 radio stations, no more than four of which may
be in the same service (AM or FM); and (4) up to five commercial radio
stations in radio markets with 14 or fewer radio stations, no more than
three of which may be in the same service (AM or FM), provided that the
entity does not own more than 50 percent of the radio stations in the
market unless the combination comprises not more than one AM and one FM
station. When determining the total number of radio stations within a
[[Page 6742]]
market, only full-power commercial and noncommercial radio stations are
counted for purposes of the rule. Radio markets are defined by Nielsen
Audio where applicable and, in Puerto Rico, the contour-overlap
methodology used in areas outside of defined and rated Nielsen Audio
Metro markets.
4. In the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Order, the Commission
concluded that local radio ownership limits promoted competition, a
public interest benefit providing a sufficient basis for retaining a
local radio ownership rule. The Commission affirmed its previous
finding that competitive local radio markets help promote viewpoint
diversity and localism and are consistent with the Commission's goal of
promoting minority and female broadcast station ownership. In the
subsequent 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Order on Reconsideration, the
Commission adopted a presumption, to be further considered in this 2018
Quadrennial Review, in favor of waiving the Local Radio Ownership Rule
for qualifying radio stations within embedded markets (i.e., smaller
markets, as defined by Nielsen Audio, that are contained within the
boundaries of a larger, parent Nielsen Audio Metro market) where the
parent market currently has multiple embedded markets (i.e., New York
and Washington, DC). Such a waiver would permit the applicant to comply
with ownership limits determined by examining only the embedded market,
and not both the embedded and parent markets. Stations would qualify
for waivers under two conditions: (1) Compliance with the numerical
ownership limits using the Nielsen Audio Metro methodology in each
embedded market, and (2) compliance with the ownership limits using the
contour-overlap methodology applicable to undefined markets in lieu of
the Commission's current parent market analysis.
5. The Commission seeks comment generally on all aspects of the
Local Radio Ownership Rule, including whether the rule remains
necessary in the public interest to promote competition and
specifically, whether there have been any changes in the marketplace
since the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review that would affect this
determination. The Commission also seeks comment on whether, in today's
radio marketplace, the rule remains necessary to promote other
Commission policy goals such as viewpoint diversity, localism, and
female and minority broadcast ownership. Commenters are asked to
explain in detail and support with evidence their reasons for any
recommended rule changes. If the rule is retained, the Commission will
analyze relevant parts of the rule to examine whether each part remains
necessary in the public interest due to competition or whether it
should be modified or eliminated. Thus, the Commission seeks comment on
each of the specific aspects of the rule's operation, including the
relevant product market, market size tiers, numerical limits, and AM/FM
subcaps, to assess whether these subparts remain necessary or whether
any of all of them should be modified or eliminated. If the rule is
retained but modified, the Commission seeks comment on whether and how
the rule changes should apply to any pending applications. The
Commission also seeks comment on whether to make permanent the interim
contour-overlap methodology used to determine ownership limits in areas
outside the boundaries of defined Nielsen Audio Metro markets, and on
the issue of embedded market transactions.
6. In anticipation of further consideration of the presumption in
favor of waiving the Local Radio Ownership Rule for radio stations
within embedded markets, the National Association of Broadcasters (NAB)
submitted a proposal to, among other things, allow an entity in the top
75 Nielsen Audio Metro markets to own or control up to eight commercial
FM stations and unlimited AM stations in any of those markets. NAB also
proposed that entities in those markets should be permitted to own up
to two additional FM stations if they participated in the Commission's
incubator program. NAB also proposed eliminating all limits on FM and
AM ownership in all other markets. NAB claimed that these rule
relaxations remove constraints on radio broadcasters' ability to
compete on a level playing field in today's digital audio world where,
NAB claimed the Commission cannot ignore, broadcast radio dominance has
declined relative to streaming services such as Pandora and Spotify,
satellite radio, podcasts, Facebook and You Tube, described as
``multiple major sources of competition for both listeners and
advertisers in the audio marketplace.'' Thus, according to NAB, the
more relevant factor for listeners has become where services can be
accessed, which is now the same for radio and other services, rather
than where services are headquartered. NAB added that allowing radio
owners to achieve economies of scale and scope would enable them to
improve their informational and entertainment programming. Other radio
broadcasters similarly claimed that digital competitors such as Google
and Facebook enjoy perceived advantages in ability to target
advertising, do not need to employ local advertising salesforces, and
had therefore captured significant shares of the local advertising
market to the detriment of local broadcast radio. Other parties argued
in opposition to NAB's proposal that allowing radio broadcasters to buy
more stations would not help them compete against internet services
such as Google and Facebook, the size of station portfolios had little
relevance to dollars allocated to free radio, advertisers did not view
radio and internet services as comparable, and radio remains the
preferred audio medium for entertainment and local news.
7. The Commission received many additional comments in response to
a request for updated information on the status of competition in the
marketplace for the delivery of audio programming in seeking to prepare
a biennial marketplace report for Congress, comments which are
incorporated into the record of this 2018 Quadrennial Review. NAB
provided information and statistical data purporting to show how
fragmented the listening market has become, and a coalition of radio
broadcasters claimed that radio listening has shrunk as audiences
divide their time among other audio providers not subject to the same
regulatory burdens as radio broadcasters. Other radio station owners
asserted that the Commission's ownership limits prevent them from
achieving the economies of scale and scope they need to compete with
satellite radio and online audio services. On the other hand,
coalitions representing musicians, recording artists, and
representatives of the music industry argued that AM/FM radio continues
to dominate the audio marketplace and that experience shows that
consolidation in the radio industry harms small broadcasters and leads
to the homogenization of programming.
8. Market Definition. The Commission concluded in the 2010/2014
Quadrennial Review Order that the broadcast radio listening market
remains the relevant product market for purposes of the Local Radio
Ownership Rule and declined to expand its definition of the market to
include non-broadcast audio sources, such as satellite radio and online
audio services. The Commission's based this conclusion on the fact that
broadcast radio stations provide ``free, over-the-air programming
tailored to the needs of the stations' local markets,'' while in
[[Page 6743]]
contrast, satellite radio is a subscription service, online audio
requires an internet connection, and neither typically provides
programming responsive to local needs and interests. Similarly, in
evaluating a broadcast radio merger of Entercom Communications and CBS
in November 2017, the Department of Justice (DOJ) also considered the
radio market, concluding that ``[m]any local and national advertisers
consider English-language broadcast radio to be a particularly
effective or important means to reach their desired customers, and do
not consider advertisements on other media, including non-English-
language broadcast radio, digital music streaming services (such as
Pandora), and television, to be reasonable substitutes.''
9. The Commission now seeks comment on these differing perspectives
of the state of the audio marketplace and on whether and how these
perspectives should affect its understanding of the market for purposes
of the Local Radio Ownership Rule. Should the Commission take DOJ's
finding on the radio market into account and if so, how? Should the
Commission continue to consider only local broadcast radio stations for
purposes of the Local Radio Ownership Rule or should it revise its
market definition to include other audio sources? Do local radio
stations face direct competition today from satellite radio and online
audio services? To what extent has radio's ability to attract listeners
and advertisers been affected by satellite radio and online audio? Do
advertisers view satellite radio and audio streaming services as
substitutes for advertising on broadcast radio? How should the impact
of internet services like Google and Facebook on local advertising
markets factor into our consideration of the Local Radio Ownership
Rule? Do consumers view non-broadcast audio services as meaningful
substitutes for local radio stations? Do non-broadcast audio services
provide programming that responds to the needs and interests of local
markets? Does radio's free, over-the-air availability make it unique or
non-substitutable in the audio marketplace? To what extent, if any,
should the Commission consider the deployment of In Band on Channel
digital radio technology and its role in enabling station owners to
expand their program offerings and increase their economies of scale
and scope? If the Commission were to revise its market definition, what
non-broadcast sources should it include, and how should it count them
or otherwise factor them into its rule for purposes of determining
market size tiers and numerical limits? Could or should the Commission
subtract from any consideration of non-broadcast sources the amount of
online audio that listeners in a local market stream from over-the-air
radio broadcasts? How would an expanded definition better serve
Commission policy goals, if at all?
10. Market Size Tiers. In the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Order,
the Commission retained the Local Radio Ownership Rule's longstanding
approach of imposing numerical ownership limits based on market size
tiers and determining market size by counting the number of commercial
and noncommercial radio stations within the market. The Commission
declined to change the rule to treat embedded markets as separate
markets. In addition, the Commission kept in place the demarcations of
the four tiers set by Congress in 1996, which draw the lines among
Nielsen Audio Metro markets at 45 plus, 30-44, 15-29, and 14 or fewer
radio stations, including noncommercial stations. The Commission seeks
comment on whether it should retain this approach of using market size
tiers, and if it does so, whether the current demarcations should
remain. Is there any reason to discontinue including noncommercial
radio stations in market counts? How well has the rule's tiered
structure served the rule's purposes, and does it promote the policy
goals of competition, localism, and viewpoint diversity in today's
radio marketplace? NAB's proposal would divide radio markets into only
two tiers--the top 75 Nielsen Audio Metro markets and all other markets
(i.e., Nielsen Audio Metro markets outside of the top 75 and all
undefined markets). What would be the advantages and disadvantages of
creating a different number of tiers, including moving from a four-
tiered to a two-tiered approach? If the Commission were to collapse
four tiers into two, should it draw the line where NAB proposes?
Commenters are invited to offer alternative proposals for a tiered
approach or for a different type of approach altogether. For example,
if the Commission changed from tiers based on station counts, should it
consider tiers based on advertising revenue, or some other factor,
rather than using Nielsen's Audio Metro market rankings as NAB
proposes, which are based on population? Would advertising revenue
provide a sufficiently stable measurement and how would such a
measurement fit with defining the relevant product market as the
broadcast radio listening market? How would the Commission and
potential applicants obtain reliable advertising revenue data for all
radio stations? Should the Commission factor non-broadcast audio
sources in any tiered approach, and if so, how should it do so? For
example: (1) If the Commission modifies its current tiers or creates
new tiers, should it account for variations across markets in broadband
access and adoption rates; (2) should the Commission treat fixed and
mobile or wired and wireless broadband the same; and (3) how granularly
can and should the Commission measure listening rates for satellite
radio and online audio services?
11. In addition, should any modifications to the current tiered
approach affect how the Commission applies the rule to areas outside
the boundaries of defined Nielsen Audio Metro markets, and if so, how?
NAB proposes removing all radio ownership limits for undefined areas.
Would NAB's proposal be consistent with Commission policy goals or
would it lead to excessive consolidation in those outside areas, and
what alternative approach could the Commission take in areas of the
country that are undefined by Nielsen Audio? Further, the contour-
overlap methodology has been successfully applied on an interim basis
to undefined markets for years and the Commission previously rejected
arguments that it permitted too much consolidation in certain markets.
Is this approach the most effective and practical for determining
ownership limits in areas outside defined Nielsen Audio Metro markets
and should the Commission therefore make it permanent? Any commenters
opposed to adopting the contour-overlap methodology on a permanent
basis should explain their reasoning and propose a detailed alternative
supported by evidence.
12. Numerical Limits. In the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Order,
the Commission declined to relax or tighten the numerical limits
restricting the number of radio stations an entity may own within a
radio market. The Commission seeks comment on whether it is necessary
as a result of competition to maintain the numerical limits for any or
all of the market size tiers. If the Commission retains existing market
tiers, are existing limits restricting the number of radio stations an
entity may own within a radio market set appropriately for each of the
market size tiers? Do the current limits adequately prevent a radio
broadcaster from amassing excessive local market power? Conversely, do
they permit sufficient growth to enable radio broadcasters to
[[Page 6744]]
obtain the additional assets they may need to improve the quality of
their service? Commenters should provide concrete, actual examples of
markets where the current limits are either too restrictive or too
lenient, explain how those examples typify other markets in that tier,
and specify the benefits to those markets that would be gained by
revising the limits.
13. The Commission also seeks comment on whether it should account
for the different signal strengths of radio stations by weighing
different classes of radio stations differently for purposes of
applying the numerical limits. For example, the Commission could
consider a Class A AM station to be worth two stations, whereas a Class
D AM station could be counted as one half a station. What would be the
costs and benefits of such an approach? What values should be accorded
to the different classes of radio stations if the Commission adopts
such an approach? The Commission previously considered a proposal to
assign different values to radio stations of different classes for
purposes of determining market size tiers and seeks comment on
assigning varying weights to different classes of radio stations when
applying the numerical limits.
14. In addition, the Commission seeks comment on NAB's proposal to
maintain the eight-station limit for the top 75 Nielsen Audio Metro
markets but to apply it only to FM stations, thereby allowing unlimited
AM ownership. NAB further proposes allowing an owner in the top 75
Nielson Audio Metro markets to acquire up to two additional FM stations
if it participates in (and, the Commission assumes, successfully
completes) the incubator program. For all other markets, NAB urges the
elimination of numerical limits for both FM and AM services. The
Commission seeks comment on all aspects of NAB's proposed changes to
the numerical limits and invites alternative proposals. What would be
the likely effects of removing FM limits in most markets? What would be
the likely effects of allowing unlimited AM ownership across all
markets? Would such actions, on balance, promote competition by
enabling owners to increase their assets, or would they harm
competition and/or ownership diversity by driving smaller broadcasters,
including minority and women owners, from the marketplace? How would
viewpoint diversity and localism be affected? The Incubator Order
rewards successful incubation of a radio station with one waiver per
market to exceed the applicable ownership limit by one station and
allows participants to use no more than one reward waiver per market.
NAB submitted its proposal to maintain the eight-station limit for the
top 75 Nielsen Audio Metro markets before the Commission adopted the
Incubator Order, so it is unclear whether NAB is suggesting that
successful incubation of one station should result in a waiver for two
stations or successful incubation of two stations should entitle an
owner to acquire two stations above the limit within the same market.
The Commission seeks comment on both possible interpretations.
15. AM/FM Subcaps. In the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Order, the
Commission retained the Local Radio Ownership Rule's AM/FM subcaps,
which prevent a broadcaster from owning more than five AM or five FM
stations in markets in the largest market tier, four AM or four FM
stations in markets in the two middle-sized tiers, or three AM or three
FM stations in markets in the smallest tier. The Commission seeks
comment on whether the AM/FM subcaps remain necessary and whether its
previous reasons for maintaining subcaps are still valid. For example,
have subcaps promoted market entry? Are subcaps still necessary given
the Commission's efforts to revitalize AM radio or has the disparity
between the FM and AM services been narrowed to an extent that the
subcaps could be relaxed or eliminated? Since its 2010/2014 Quadrennial
Review, the Commission has granted over 1,000 applications to acquire
and relocate FM translators to rebroadcast AM stations. Should the
expanded and improved coverage of those AM stations affect the analysis
of subcaps? Conversely, data from the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review
indicated that the transition to digital radio actually exacerbated the
divide between the services because AM stations have been slower to
adopt digital radio technology. What is the import of the current
status of the digital radio transition for evaluating the subcaps? If
subcaps continue to promote competition or ownership diversity, or
otherwise serve the public interest, are they currently set at the
appropriate levels?
16. If the Commission revises the Local Radio Ownership Rule,
should the modified rule include AM or FM subcaps, and if so, how
should they be applied? NAB's proposal essentially would eliminate AM
subcaps in all markets and retain FM subcaps in only the top 75
markets. NAB does not explain why it would distinguish the FM service
for restricted ownership in the top markets rather than limit the total
number of radio stations in those markets regardless of service, and
the Commission seeks comment on whether the proposal is supported by
technical or marketplace differences between the services. In a letter
filed shortly after NAB submitted its proposal, the owner of a network
of AM stations argued that removing and/or relaxing FM subcaps would
harm the AM service by facilitating the migration of content to the FM
service. Concurring with that view, iHeartMedia urges the Commission to
loosen restrictions on AM ownership while retaining the existing FM
subcaps, arguing that doing so would be consistent with the
Commission's efforts to revitalize AM radio. Considering these
competing positions, the Commission seeks comment on what limits, if
any, should apply to AM and FM ownership, whether to retain the current
market size tiers and numerical limits, and on whether and how any
proposed revisions to the Local Radio Ownership Rule should include
such limits.
17. Embedded Markets. Owners of radio stations in embedded markets
within a parent market, which currently exist only in New York and
Washington, DC, must comply with the Local Radio Ownership Rule's
numerical limits for both the embedded market and the parent market. In
response to the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Further Notice of Proposed
Rulemaking (FNPRM), Connoisseur Media argued that because radio
stations within different embedded markets within a parent market have
little or no contour overlap and may reach different populations, the
Commission's analysis of a proposed acquisition in one embedded market
should not include stations owned in the other embedded markets within
the same parent market. In the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Order on
Reconsideration, the Commission declined to adopt an across-the-board
change to its embedded market methodology, but adopted a waiver
standard whereby embedded market transactions in markets with multiple
embedded markets would be presumed to be in the public interest if they
met a two-prong test proposed by Connoisseur: (1) As with the
Commission's current methodology for embedded markets, a radio station
owner seeking a rule waiver must comply with the applicable numerical
ownership limit in each embedded market using the Nielsen Audio Metro
methodology; and (2) instead of then also demonstrating compliance with
the applicable numerical ownership limit based on the Commission's
parent
[[Page 6745]]
market analysis, the applicant must show that it also complies with the
ownership limits as determined by the contour-overlap methodology
ordinarily applicable in undefined markets. The Commission adopted this
presumptive waiver standard on an interim basis pending the outcome of
this 2018 Quadrennial Review proceeding.
18. Accordingly, the Commission seeks comment on how to address the
issue of embedded market transactions. If the Commission retains a
Local Radio Ownership Rule, how should it apply going forward to radios
station in markets that contain multiple embedded markets, currently
New York and Washington, DC? Should the presumptive waiver standard
become permanent? Should it be modified in any way? Should it apply to
all current and future markets that contain multiple embedded markets,
or should its application be limited to the two existing parent markets
with multiple embedded markets? How do competition, diversity, and
localism considerations affect the question? Embedded market
designations can be updated and modified by Nielsen Audio as market
conditions change, and Nielsen Audio's radio station customers can
request the designation of a new embedded market. How could the
Commission guard against purchasers taking advantage of an anticipated
designation of a new embedded market in a manner that would thwart the
purpose of the current ownership limits? For example, in the event that
Nielsen Audio creates new, additional situations with multiple embedded
markets within a larger parent market, should there be a waiting period
before applicants can take advantage of that change in circumstance,
similar to the waiting period applicable to changes in the stations
reported as ``home'' to a Nielsen Audio Metro market? If the Commission
adopts any change to its approach to embedded markets, should the
change also apply to markets with a single embedded market? Is there a
distinction between markets with one embedded market and markets with
multiple embedded markets such that the Commission should vary its
approach between those situations?
19. In the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Order on Reconsideration,
the Commission expressed its intent to consider in this 2018
Quadrennial Review an alternate NAB proposal that stations licensed in
embedded markets with signal coverage of less than 50 percent of the
parent market's population not be considered part of the parent market
for purposes of local ownership limit compliance calculations. The
Commission seeks comment on whether it should adopt such an approach or
any other across-the-board rule changes regarding embedded markets. Is
there a need to implement a rule change that carves out a blanket
exception to the current methodology given that there are only two
parent markets containing multiple embedded markets? Or is a permanent
presumptive waiver standard an adequate solution given how narrow its
use is likely to be? The Commission seeks comment on the potential
advantages and disadvantages of these various approaches and invites
proposals for other ways to address embedded market transactions.
20. Minority and Female Ownership. In the 2010/2014 Quadrennial
Review Order, the Commission found the current Local Radio Ownership
Rule to be consistent with its goal of promoting minority and female
ownership of broadcast radio stations, observing that the rule, while
competition-based, indirectly promotes viewpoint diversity by
facilitating ``the presence of independently owned broadcast radio
stations in the local market, thereby increasing the likelihood of a
variety of viewpoints and preserving ownership opportunities for new
entrants.'' It pointed to AM subcaps in particular as elements of the
rule that foster new entry. Because available data did not show that
stricter limits would increase minority and female radio ownership,
however, the Commission chose not to tighten the rule. Similarly, the
Commission found no indication of a causal link between Congress'
loosening of local radio limits in 1996 and the increase in ownership
diversity since then that would justify loosening the rules. The
Commission seeks comment on whether any new information has become
available that would cause us to reevaluate these conclusions. The
Commission also seeks comment on how retaining or modifying the Local
Radio Ownership Rule might affect broadcast radio ownership and entry
by small business owners, if at all.
21. Local Television Ownership Rule. The Local Television Ownership
Rule allows an entity to own up to two television stations in the same
Nielsen Designated Market Area (DMA) (a group of counties forming an
exclusive geographic area to which the Nielsen Company assigns each
broadcast television station) if: (1) The digital noise limited service
contours (NLSCs) of the stations (as determined by Sec. 73.622(e) of
the Commission's rules) do not overlap; or (2) at the time the
application to acquire or construct the station(s) is filed, at least
one of the stations is not ranked among the top-four stations in the
DMA, based on the most recent all-day (9 a.m.-midnight) audience share,
as measured by Nielsen Media Research or by any comparable
professional, accepted audience ratings service. With respect to the
latter provision--the Top-Four Prohibition--an applicant may request
that the Commission examine the facts and circumstances in a market
regarding a particular transaction and, based on the showing made by
the applicant in a particular case, make a finding that permitting an
entity to directly or indirectly own, operate, or control two top-four
television stations licensed in the same DMA would serve the public
interest, convenience, and necessity. The Commission considers showings
that the Top-Four Prohibition should not apply due to specific
circumstances in a local market or with respect to a specific
transaction on a case-by-case basis.
22. The Commission found in the 2018 Quadrennial Review Order on
Reconsideration that local television ownership limits remained
necessary to promote competition among broadcast stations in local
television markets, finding that such competition leads stations to
invest in better and more locally tailored programming and to compete
for advertising revenue and retransmission consent fees. The Commission
also determined, however, that the existing rule required modification
to ensure that television broadcasters could achieve efficiencies to
make such improvements in an evolving video marketplace. The Commission
therefore repealed the provision of the previous rule requiring at
least eight independently owned television stations to remain in a DMA
after any station acquisition in the DMA, finding that this Eight-
Voices test was unsupported by the record or reasoned analysis and was
no longer necessary in the public interest. The Commission also added
flexibility to the application of the Top-Four Prohibition by adopting
the case-by-case analysis mentioned above.
23. First, the Commission seeks comment on whether the current
version of the Local Television Ownership Rule is necessary in the
public interest as a result of competition. In earlier media ownership
reviews, broadcasters argued that local television ownership
restrictions prevent them from competing effectively, while other
commenters supported retention of limits based on the need to prevent
excessive consolidation of television stations due to the unique nature
of their free, over-
[[Page 6746]]
the-air programming provided on spectrum licensed for public benefit.
The Commission seeks comment on how developments in the video
programming industry since the last quadrennial review have affected
whether the Local Television Ownership Rule is necessary as a result of
competition and to promote localism and viewpoint diversity among local
broadcast television stations. The Commission seeks comment on whether
promoting competition among television stations in local viewing
markets continues to be the proper framework within which to consider
the rule, and if so, what forms of competition it should take into
account under such a framework. For instance, how, if at all, should
the Commission consider competition among television stations for
viewers, advertisers, retransmission consent fees, network affiliation,
the provision of local news or other programming, the production or
acquisition of programming, innovation, or any other form of
competition?
24. The Commission also seeks comment on whether the Local
Television Ownership Rule is necessary to promote localism or viewpoint
diversity. The Commission has previously stated that a competition-
based rule, while not designed specifically to promote localism or
viewpoint diversity, may still have such an effect. Has the prior
reliance on competition as the primary policy goal of the Local
Television Ownership Rule also served as a proxy for preserving a
certain level of localism or viewpoint diversity in local television
markets that might otherwise be lost were we to find the rule no longer
necessary for competition purposes?
25. The Commission seeks comment on whether a competition-based
Local Television Ownership Rule promotes the production or provision of
local programming. Localism has been a cornerstone of the Commission's
broadcast regulation for decades, with the Commission finding that
broadcast licensees have an obligation to air programming that is
responsive to the needs and interests of their communities of license.
Does promoting competition among broadcast stations incentivize
stations to produce and improve local programming? Could or does
competition from non-broadcast video sources, which have no local
programming requirements, create the same incentives to produce and
improve local programming?
26. If the Commission decides to retain the Local Television
Ownership Rule, it will analyze the relevant parts of the rule to
examine whether each particular provision similarly remains necessary
in the public interest as a result of competition or whether it should
be modified or eliminated. Thus, the Commission seeks comment on
specific aspects of the rule's operation, including the relevant
product market, numerical limits, and the Top-Four Prohibition, to
assess whether these subparts remain necessary or whether any or all of
them should be modified or eliminated. The Commission also asks whether
developments in the video programming industry involving multicasting,
satellite stations, low power stations, and the next generation
transmission standard have any implications on the Local Television
Ownership Rule or its subparts.
27. Market Definition. In the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Order on
Reconsideration, the Commission found that a rule to preserve
competition among local broadcast television stations was still
warranted, but also noted that it was not free to retain the rule
without adjustments to account for marketplace changes outside the
local broadcast television market. The Commission also found that non-
broadcast video offerings do not serve as meaningful substitutes for
local broadcast television, and noted that video programming delivered
by multichannel video programming distributors (MVPDs) is generally
uniform across all markets, as is programming provided by online video
distributors (OVDs). The Commission stated that unlike local broadcast
stations, MVPDs and OVDs were not likely to make programming decisions
based on conditions or preferences in local markets, but indicated that
this conclusion could change in a future proceeding with a different
record.
28. The Commission now seeks comment on relevant marketplace
changes and whether and how it should take such changes into account.
The Commission seeks comment on the appropriate product market for
reviewing the Local Television Ownership Rule, including whether to
include more than broadcast video programming and what market
participants to consider. In light of the evolving video marketplace,
the Commission also seeks comment on its prior findings in the 2010/
2014 Quadrennial Review Order, and whether and to what extent non-
broadcast sources of video programming should be considered competitors
to broadcast television stations. Do consumers consider broadcast
television to be interchangeable with other sources of programming? If
so, what other sources of video programming should be included in the
analysis of a local product market? What factors should the Commission
consider in analyzing non-broadcast sources of video programming?
Should the Commission distinguish between linear (scheduled) and non-
linear (i.e., video-on-demand) distributors of video? In which product
markets, if any, do non-broadcast video programmers compete with
broadcast television programmers? Does broadcast television offer any
programming for which there is no substitute available from non-
broadcast video programmers? Based on Nielsen and NAB data, the
Commission noted in the Eighteenth Video Competition Report the
increasing number of households relying on broadcast rather than MVPD
service. To what extent do consumers rely on broadcast television as
their primary, or only, source of video programming? The Commission
previously noted that broadband penetration is relevant when
considering whether on-line platforms are meaningful substitutes for
local broadcast. Is the availability of non-broadcast video comparable
to that of broadcast television? Do viewers rely on or consume
programming from local broadcast stations in a manner different from
other sources of, potentially, non-local video programming? In
addition, do any non-broadcast video programmers make programming
decisions based on local markets or the actions of individual local
television stations (i.e., a cable operator deciding to carry local
sporting events not covered by the local broadcaster)?
29. The Commission also found in the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review
Order that arguments by broadcasters that advertisers no longer
distinguish between local broadcast television and non-broadcast video
programming when deciding how to spend on local advertising were not
supported by the record. Thus, the Commission seeks comment on whether
and to what extent non-broadcast sources of video programming should be
considered competitors to broadcast television stations. The Commission
also asks how advertisers select between local broadcast and non-
broadcast sources of programming and seeks studies and data that it can
use to assess substitutability in local advertising among all sources
of video in a DMA. The Commission seeks comment and new data about
whether and how various video programming providers compete for local
advertising revenue.
30. Given the Commission's prior findings in the 2010/2014 Biennial
Review Order that competition within local markets can produce better
[[Page 6747]]
programming and programming tailored to local needs and interests from
which viewers benefit, the Commission seeks comment on whether, in
evaluating the Local Television Ownership Rule, it should consider
sources of local news and other local programming as a relevant product
market. What are the most prominent sources of local news and local
programming beyond broadcast television? Should non-video providers of
news and information--such as radio, newspapers, internet websites, and
social media platforms--be examined in the product market analysis? To
what extent do potential viewers rely for local news on these
alternative sources? Given Knight Foundation reports that online-only
local news websites have limited impact, are these sources originators
of local programming, or do they simply aggregate or utilize content
generated by traditional local news sources? Are non-broadcast sources
of local programming available in all DMAs or are they just in major
markets? Is the depth of any coverage of local issues by non-broadcast
platforms consistent across DMAs? The Commission seeks comment on the
availability and variety of local video programming in each Nielsen DMA
and on how the Commission would, and if it should, evaluate local
programming for purposes of any programming-based analysis. The
Commission seeks comment on whether defining the local product market
for our television ownership rules to include specific types of
programming would raise First Amendment concerns.
31. What measures could the Commission use to assess competition
among sources of local video programming or other local content? What
data sources might the Commission use to determine which sources
consumers consider substitutes? Given the lack of a single, accepted,
industry-wide standard for measuring online viewership, how should the
Commission account for various providers of news, information, and
video programming to the extent that some entities, such as OVDs and
websites, may lack an industry standard for measuring viewership and
engagement?
32. The Commission also seeks comment on the relationship between
its local television ownership market definition and any changes
thereto, and the market definition and analysis used by DOJ, which
examines local television broadcasters competing in the spot
advertising market. The Commission stated in the 2010/2014 Quadrennial
Review Order that its market definition when evaluating broadcast
television mergers is like DOJ's in that the scope of the Commission's
rule is similarly limited to local television broadcast stations. DOJ's
analysis, however, has historically focused on competition for
advertising, whereas the Commission's analysis focuses on multiple
factors, including audience share. Recently in evaluating the
combination of Nexstar and Media General, DOJ also looked at
competition for retransmission consent licensing fees in local
television markets. The Commission seeks comment on whether and how
DOJ's analytical framework should inform its own, and vice versa. Are
there ways in which the Commission's current rule is either consistent
or inconsistent with antitrust principles? Do other public interest
considerations support the rule?
33. Numerical Limit. Currently, a broadcast licensee can own up to
two television stations (a duopoly) in a DMA, subject to the
requirements of the Local Television Ownership Rule. In the 2010/2014
Quadrennial Review Order, the Commission concluded that changes in the
local television market demonstrated by the record were insufficient to
justify either tightening or loosening this numerical limit. The
Commission therefore seeks comment on whether subsequent changes in the
video programming industry now support changes to the numerical limit.
If the Commission finds that retaining a local television rule remains
in the public interest, should it change the numerical limit on how
many stations may be owned in a DMA?
34. Top-Four Prohibition. The Commission found in the 2010/2014
Quadrennial Review Order that ratings data supported the Local
Television Ownership Rule's focus on the top-four rated full power
television stations in a market, that there typically remained a
significant ``cushion'' of audience share points that separated the
top-four stations in a market from the fifth-ranked station and below,
and that the record supported potential harms associated with top-four
combinations. The Commission seeks comment on the applicability of
these previous conclusions based on new, updated ratings data and/or
examples of existing commonly owned top-four station combinations. If
the Commission retains a local television ownership rule, should the
top four prohibition be retained or modified?
35. In the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Order on Reconsideration,
the Commission recognized that rigid application of the Top-Four
Prohibition in all DMAs may not be supported by the unique conditions
present in certain DMAs or with respect to certain transactions, and
accordingly adopted a hybrid approach to allow applicants to seek a
case-by-case examination of a proposed combination that would otherwise
be prohibited by the Top-Four Prohibition. The Commission stated that
the types of information applicants could provide on competition in the
local market in such examinations included: (1) Ratings share data of
the stations proposed to be combined compared with other stations in
the market; (2) revenue share data of the stations proposed to be
combined compared with other stations in the market, including
advertising (on-air and digital) and retransmission consent fees; (3)
market characteristics, such as population and the number and types of
broadcast television stations serving the market (including any strong
competitors outside the top-four rated broadcast television stations);
(4) the likely effects on programming meeting the needs and interests
of the community; and (5) any other circumstances impacting the market,
particularly any disparities primarily impacting small and mid-sized
markets.
36. The Commission asks whether flexibility in applying the Top-
Four prohibition remains necessary and, if so, whether the case-by-case
approach is the most effective way to achieve it. If the Commission
finds that a case-by-case analysis is the best approach, do the types
of information listed in the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Order on
Reconsideration serve as reliable factors in determining whether a top-
four combination would serve the public interest? If so, should some
factors be weighed more heavily than others in the analysis? Are there
factors in addition to the examples provided in the 2010/2014
Quadrennial Review Order on Reconsideration that the Commission should
consider? What kinds of data should licensees provide to support their
showings? Should the Commission adopt a more rigid set of criteria for
its case-by-case determination?
37. Alternatively, should the Commission avoid a case-by-case or
hybrid approach and establish a bright-line test that would permit
common ownership of two top-four stations in all cases, or in
particular markets or circumstances? For example, should the Commission
permit common ownership of the fourth-ranked station in a market and
either the second-ranked station or third-ranked station in that same
market? Should the Commission allow combinations between the second-
ranked station or third-ranked station in the same market? Should such
combinations only be permitted in
[[Page 6748]]
smaller markets where there is less advertising revenue available to
support programming and station operations? The Commission also seeks
comment on whether it should create a presumption for permitting common
ownership of two top-four stations if certain conditions are met. What
conditions should the Commission consider in determining if a
combination would not negatively impact competition? For example,
should the Commission presume that a combination is permissible if the
combined stations' share of the audience and/or advertising market
share does not exceed a certain threshold?
38. If the Commission either retains the case-by-case approach or
adopts a bright-line test, it seeks comment on how to analyze
competition in local television markets. In considering the effect of
top-four combinations on local advertising markets, the Commission
seeks studies that estimate the elasticity of demand for local
advertising. In the absence of such studies, what data sources or types
of data might the Commission use to assess substitutability in local
advertising across dayparts, program types, and stations? What
measures, in addition to viewership share, could be used to assess
competition between stations in local programming? What data sources
might we use to determine which programs or stations viewers consider
substitutes?
39. A top-four combination may have different effects on
competition among broadcast stations for viewers of different types of
programming, for instance, local programming, network programming, and
syndicated programming. Should the Commission weigh each competitive
effect and, if so, how? If the Commission considers specific categories
of programming, should it look at the viewership of each type of
programming, the amount of revenue generated for the local station by
each type of programming, both, or something else? Top-four
combinations may also affect the quantity or quality of local
programming available in the market. Although intended primarily to
promote competition, does the Top-Four Prohibition also preserve, as a
byproduct, a sufficient level of localism or viewpoint diversity in
local markets? The Commission seeks comment on whether and how it
should consider elimination of an independent local news operation or a
reduction in local news programming.
40. The Commission also seeks comment on whether and how it should
weigh any effect on retransmission consent negotiations in evaluating
competitive effects under the Commission's case-by-case approach to
evaluating top-four station combinations. Commenters in proceedings
involving potential top-four station combinations consistently have
raised the issue of potential retransmission consent fee increases
because of reduced competition between stations and undue bargaining
leverage for stations if commonly owned top-four stations are able to
negotiate such fees jointly as a result of the combination. In its
Nexstar-Media General review, DOJ also recognized that common ownership
of two major broadcast network affiliates can lead to diminished
competition in the negotiation of retransmission agreements with MVPDs
in local television markets. The Commission therefore seeks comment on
whether and how it should weigh the effect on retransmission consent
negotiations in evaluating top-four station combinations under its
case-by-case approach. Should the Commission maintain the Top-Four
Prohibition for purposes of preventing any potential competitive harms
caused by joint negotiation of retransmission consent fees by two
commonly owned top-four stations in a DMA, and would such an approach
be inconsistent with congressional intent in prohibiting joint
negotiation only when conducted by non-commonly owned stations in the
STELA Reauthorization Act of 2014?
41. If the Commission keeps the Top-Four Prohibition or a similar
rule that relies on the ranking of stations by audience share or
viewership, should any specific provisions of the rule be modified? The
rule currently determines a station's in-market ranking based on the
most recent all-day (9 a.m.-midnight) audience share, as measured by
Nielsen Media Research. The Commission seeks comment on whether this
data point is still the most useful for accurately determining a
station's ranking for purposes of the Top-Four Prohibition. Have there
been changes in the industry that necessitate examining different data?
The Commission also seeks comment on whether and how it should account
for instances where a station makes use of multicast streams, satellite
stations, or translators. Should the ratings of these stations or
streams be combined with the ratings of the primary station or stream
to determine the station's ratings in the DMA? Why or why not? Lastly,
based on Commission staff review of Nielsen data, there are instances
where noncommercial television stations have audience shares comparable
to those of commercial stations. Should the Commission distinguish
between commercial and noncommercial stations for purposes of the Top-
Four Prohibition? Why or why not?
42. The Commission seeks comment on whether to provide
clarification of the phrase ``at the time the application to acquire or
construct the station(s) is filed.'' Should entities filing an
application submit as support audience share data for the most recent
month, week, or sweeps period in relation to the date when the
application was submitted to the Commission? Should the time frame for
the submitted data be required to show a longer period? For example,
should the Commission require applicants to submit ratings data over a
three-year period to demonstrate that a station truly is or is not
ranked among the top-four stations in the DMA ``at the time the
application to acquire or construct the station(s) is filed'' as
suggested in the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Order on Reconsideration?
If not, should the Commission take another approach to prevent
circumvention of the Top-Four Prohibition's requirements based on
anomalous data? Should it rely on the most recent period solely as a
presumption, which might be rebutted by interested parties?
43. Given the longstanding nature of the Top-Four Prohibition, much
of the discussion in this section focuses on the continued
applicability of that rule and ways that it might be adjusted or
clarified to apply in the current video marketplace. The Commission
also seeks comment on alternatives to the Top-Four Prohibition. Should
common ownership of two stations in a market be permitted when at least
one of the stations is not ranked among the top-three stations in the
market, or among the top-two? What economic data support establishing
such a top-three approach, considering the significant differences in
national audience share between the top-four national networks and
others? Should the Commission distinguish between stations located in
larger Nielsen DMAs and those in mid- to small-sized DMAs by adopting a
tiered approach to application of any ranking-based prohibition? Should
common ownership be permitted when there is a certain number of non-
broadcast local video programing sources in a DMA? The Commission seeks
comment on how these and any other proposals supported by the record
would promote and protect competition in local television markets.
44. Multicasting. As a result of the digital television transition,
all full-power television stations have the ability to use their
available spectrum to
[[Page 6749]]
broadcast not only their main program stream but also, if they choose,
additional program streams--an activity commonly referred to as
multicasting. In the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Order the Commission
distinguished between the ability to multicast and ownership of a
separate broadcast station and declined to impose restrictions on local
television station ownership based on the ability to multicast. Because
the record indicated that dual affiliations involving two Big Four
networks (ABC, CBS, Fox, and NBC) via multicasting were generally
limited to smaller markets where there was an insufficient number of
full-power commercial television stations to accommodate each Big Four
network or where other unique marketplace factors led to creating the
dual affiliation, the Commission declined to regulate dual affiliations
through multicasting, even in instances where a licensee is affiliated
with more than one of the Big Four networks. The Commission stated,
however, that it would continue to monitor this issue and act in the
future, if appropriate.
45. The Commission now seeks comment on how technical and other
developments in the broadcast industry have affected multicasting. Are
some multicast streams functioning as the equivalent of separate
broadcast stations? Multicasting has enabled broadcasters to bring more
programming to consumers, particularly in smaller, rural markets, by
expanding the availability of the four major networks and newer
networks. Based on Commission staff review of Nielsen data, there are
at least several dozen DMAs where a single entity holds affiliations
with two Big Four networks by using a multicast stream to carry the
second signal. Thus, the Commission seeks comment on the
characteristics of DMAs where major network affiliations are carried on
multicast streams. Are there certain markets where this practice is
more commonplace? Do dual affiliations with major networks remains
limited to smaller markets or has the practice become more widespread?
The Commission asks whether and how it should evaluate multicast
streams for purposes of the Local Television Ownership Rule.
46. Satellite Stations. Television satellite stations are full-
power broadcast stations authorized under Part 73 of the Commission's
rules that generally retransmit some or all of the programming of
another television station, known as the parent station, which
typically is commonly owned or operated with the satellite station.
Satellite stations are exempt from the Local Television Ownership Rule,
and the Commission seeks comment on their use to carry two Big Four
networks in a market. For instance, how should the Commission treat a
situation in which a licensee utilizes multicasting to air two Big Four
networks on a parent station (e.g., one on the primary stream and one
on a multicast stream), and airs the same two Big Four networks on a
satellite station? How prevalent is this practice, and is it consistent
with the purposes behind allowing satellite stations in the first
place, which are generally intended to bring over-the-air television
service to unserved areas? Are there benefits to allowing this practice
that outweigh any potential harms? The Commission seeks comment on
whether this issue should be addressed through modification of the
satellite exemption to the Local Television Ownership Rule or,
alternatively, in the context of the satellite authorization process.
47. Low Power Television Stations. Changes in industry practice and
technological advances may have extended the reach and enhanced the
capabilities of low power and translator television broadcast stations
that are currently exempt from local television ownership limits. Based
on a review of Nielsen data by Commission staff, there are a
significant number of low power stations affiliated with a Big Four
network. Because of this affiliation, MVPDs are likely willing to carry
the low power stations, which qualify for must-carry on cable systems
under very limited circumstances, despite their status. If low power
stations can in this way become the functional equivalent of full power
stations in certain instances, should the Commission account for the
number of low power television stations as part of its Local Television
Ownership Rule in some way, and if so, how? For instance, should a low
power station that is ranked among the top four stations in audience
share in a DMA be counted as a top-four station for purposes of the
Top-Four Prohibition?
48. Next Generation Broadcast Television Transmission Standard.
Currently, the broadcast television industry is developing a new
transmission standard called Advanced Television Systems Committee
(ATSC) 3.0 with the intent of merging the capabilities of over-the-air
broadcasting with the broadband viewing and information delivery
methods of the internet, using the same 6 MHz channels presently
allocated for DTV service. According to ATSC 3.0 advocates, the new
standard has the potential to improve broadcast signal reception
greatly, particularly on mobile devices and television receivers
without outdoor antennas. ATSC 3.0 will enable broadcasters to offer
enhanced and innovative new features to consumers, including Ultra High
Definition (UHD) picture and immersive audio, more localized
programming content, an advanced emergency alert system (EAS) capable
of waking up sleeping devices to warn consumers of imminent
emergencies, better accessibility options, and interactive services.
49. The Commission seeks comment on the implications, if any, of
the new broadcast television transmission standard on the Local
Television Ownership Rule. The Commission also seeks comment on whether
any provisions of the Local Television Ownership Rule potentially could
affect adoption and deployment of the new transmission standard. How,
if at all, should the Commission in the context of local television
ownership consider the decisions of television broadcasters to adopt
voluntarily the ATSC 3.0 transmission standard?
50. Broadcast Spectrum Auction. In the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review
Order, the Commission stated that it could not yet determine how the
incentive auction would affect the Local Television Ownership Rule. On
April 13, 2017, the Commission released a public notice announcing the
results of the reverse and forward auctions and the repacking of the
broadcast television spectrum. Pursuant to the statute authorizing the
incentive auction, that public notice marked the auction's completion
and the start of the 39-month post-auction transition period. Given
completion of the auction and the subsequent surrender of spectrum and/
or initiation of channel-sharing agreements, the Commission seeks
comment on whether the auction's effects on local television ownership
have any implication on retention or modification of the Local
Television Ownership Rule.
51. Shared Service Agreements. In the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review
Order, the Commission adopted a definition of shared service agreements
(SSAs) and, despite opposition from broadcasters, a requirement that
commercial television stations disclose SSAs by placing them in their
online public inspection files. The Commission also found it lacked
knowledge about the content, scope, and prevalence of SSAs that kept it
from evaluating the impact of these agreements, if any, on its policy
goals with respect to broadcast ownership. The 2010/2014 Quadrennial
Review Order on Reconsideration upheld the disclosure requirement,
which took effect on March 23, 2018. The Commission now seeks comment
on
[[Page 6750]]
what action, if any, it should take on SSAs in the context of this 2018
review of the Local Television Ownership Rule. Should the Commission
retain or eliminate the SSA filing requirement? What, if anything, have
commenters learned from filing the agreements so far?
52. Minority and Female Ownership. The Commission stated in the
2010/2014 Quadrennial Order that, while the Local Television Ownership
Rule promotes competition among broadcast television stations in local
markets and is not meant to preserve or create specific amounts of
minority and female ownership, the rule nevertheless promotes
opportunities for diversity in local television ownership. The
Commission concluded that the competition-based rule helps to ensure
the presence of independently owned broadcast television stations in
the local market, thereby indirectly increasing the likelihood of a
variety of viewpoints and preserving ownership opportunities for new
entrants. The record held no data indicating that the duopoly rule has
reduced minority ownership or suggested that a return to the single
station per licensee rule would increase ownership opportunities for
minorities and women. While the data did indicate an increase in
minority ownership following relaxation of the Local Television
Ownership Rule, there was no evidence in the record that established a
causal connection. The Commission now asks how retaining, modifying, or
eliminating the local television rule would affect broadcast television
ownership and entry by minority and female owners, if at all. The
Commission seeks data and an updated record on the effects of the Local
Television Ownership Rule on minority and female broadcast ownership
and entry. Finally, the Commission seeks comment on how retaining or
modifying the rule might affect broadcast television ownership and
entry by small business owners, if at all.
53. Dual Network Rule. The Dual Network Rule permits common
ownership of multiple broadcast networks, but effectively prohibits a
merger between or among the Big Four networks. In the 2010/2014
Quadrennial Review Order, the Commission concluded that the Dual
Network Rule continues to be necessary in the public interest to
promote competition and localism. With respect to competition, the
Commission found the rule necessary to promote both competition in the
provision of primetime entertainment programming and the sale of
national advertising. With respect to localism, the Commission found
that the rule was necessary to preserve the balance of power between
the Big Four networks and their local affiliates.
54. In conducting its analysis of whether the Dual Network Rule
remains necessary, the Commission traditionally has considered
broadcast networks as participating in the video marketplace in two
ways: (1) Assembling and distributing a collection of programming
suitable for large, national audiences, and (2) selling advertising
based on this programming to large, national advertisers. Does the Dual
Network Rule continue to be relevant to competition or network behavior
in either or both of these segments? The Commission concluded in the
2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Order that ``the primetime entertainment
programming provided by the Big Four broadcast networks and national
television advertising time are each a distinct product--the
availability, price, and quality of which could be restricted, to the
detriment of consumers, if two [Big Four broadcast networks] were
permitted to merge.'' Does this conclusion remain valid? The Commission
also generally seeks comment on whether the Dual Network Rule remains
necessary to promote its goals of competition, viewpoint diversity and
localism, and on whether the benefits of the rule outweigh any costs.
55. Regarding viewership, in the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Order
the Commission found, based on Nielsen data, that no cable programming
could deliver primetime audiences on par with, let alone greater than,
the primetime audiences delivered by the Big Four networks. The
Commission's Eighteenth Video Competition Report, based on 2015 data,
showed that broadcast affiliates still draw the largest share of total
day and prime time viewing audiences in relation to independent
stations and non-commercial and cable networks. The 2010/2014
Quadrennial Review Order also found a continued wide disparity in the
advertising rates and revenue earned by the Big Four networks and other
broadcast and cable networks. The Commission seeks more current data on
these topics. Do these or other recent developments have any
implications for the Commission's competition rationale underlying the
Dual Network Rule?
56. The Commission also found in the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review
Order and in previous reviews of the Dual Network Rule that the Big
Four networks operate as a ``strategic group'' in the national
advertising market and that they largely compete among themselves for
the most significant portion of the national advertising market, namely
advertisers that seek to reach national mass audiences. The Commission
further found that the programming provided by the Big Four networks
was a distinct product that, when compared to other broadcast and cable
programming, had a unique ability to regularly attract large prime-time
audiences and thus command higher advertising rates. Does the
Commission's ``strategic group'' finding still hold true? Given the
increasing number of video programmers in today's market, as well as
the increasing popularity of their programming, is network broadcast
programming still a distinct product? Does nightly network news
programming, or any other programming, distinguish the broadcast
networks, or are consumers now turning to other news or programming
sources that remove this distinction? Are there other producers of mass
audience programming such that a merger between two of the Big Four
networks would no longer harm competition for national advertising? In
the past, the Commission reviewed programming audience shares and the
advertising rates and revenues of various programmers in making this
determination. Should the Commission continue to rely on these data, or
are there other data or metrics it should consider? Are there better
sources of relevant data than the Commission has considered in the
past?
57. One of the biggest changes in the video programming market has
been online distribution of programming from a variety of sources.
Today, OVDs--including linear multichannel streaming services, both
those from social media companies and other online platforms, and
direct-to-consumer offerings by broadcast networks themselves--reach
millions of consumers. Digital advertising on these or other online
platforms is steadily increasing in market and revenue share. How, if
at all, have these changes affected competition for national broadcast
television advertising? The Commission seeks comment on whether and how
any such changes should affect our Dual Network Rule.
58. The Commission also seeks comment on whether recent
developments in the video programming and national advertising markets
suggest that the Dual Network Rule should be modified to promote
competition or eliminated. If the rule is modified, what changes should
we make? Should networks be removed from or added to the rule? If so,
which networks? What would be the basis for eliminating the
[[Page 6751]]
rule? If the rule were eliminated, would antitrust statutes or any
other statutes, rules, or policies serve as a sufficient backstop to
prevent undue consolidation between or among the Big Four networks? Why
or why not?
59. The Commission also seeks comment on whether The Dual Network
Rule remains necessary to promote localism, in particular by
maintaining a balance of power between the Big Four networks and their
local affiliates. To reach the largest possible national audience, the
Big Four networks acquire their own broadcast stations, usually in the
largest television markets, and enter into affiliation agreements with
station owners throughout the rest of the country. Through affiliation,
a model which has existed for more than fifty years, networks benefit
through wide delivery of their programming, and network affiliates
benefit by gaining access to high-quality programming. The Commission
has found in previous media ownership rule reviews that the network-
affiliate model balances competing interests: Networks have an economic
incentive to ensure that programming appeals to a mass, nationwide
audience while affiliates have an economic incentive to tailor
programming to their local audiences and influence network programming
choices to ensure that the programming serves local needs and
interests. Affiliates also may decide individually to preempt network
programming for other programming better serving the local audience.
The Commission now seeks comment on whether these specific conclusions,
and the Commission's general conclusion that the Dual Network Rule is
needed to keep the balance of bargaining power between the Big Four
networks and their affiliates, remain true in today's video
marketplace.
60. Evidence submitted in the Commission's review of the Comcast-
NBCU merger suggested that broadcast network affiliation remains sought
after and critical to many local stations' success. Also, while
advertising revenue remains essential to broadcast stations, the
Eighteenth Video Competition Report showed that retransmission consent
revenues now represent a much greater proportion of total revenue for
many broadcast stations than previously, and stations with Big Four
network affiliations often receive the lion's share of retransmission
consent dollars from MVPDs in a local market. The Eighteenth Video
Competition Report also showed that, whereas local affiliates were once
paid by networks to distribute network programming, today networks seek
and receive compensation from their affiliates in the form of reverse
compensation payments. According to one estimate by SNL Kagan, total
industrywide reverse compensation payments paid by affiliates to
broadcast networks have increased from roughly $300 million in 2010 to
$2.9 billion in 2017. There is some evidence too that networks now
exert leverage through oversight or approval of affiliate
retransmission consent negotiations, and although not common, in some
instances in recent years a network dropped or threatened to drop a
local affiliate to launch a network O&O station in the same market. To
what extent do networks extract a share of retransmission consent
payments received by their affiliates? How, if at all, should the Dual
Network Rule account for these or other recent changes to the network/
affiliate relationship?
61. In addition, the rise of online video options in recent years
also may have altered the network-affiliate dynamic. As stated above,
OVDs now reach millions of consumers, creating new opportunities for
networks to achieve widespread distribution without the direct
involvement of network affiliates. In the broadcast-MVPD world of
retransmission consent, local affiliates may have some recourse against
broadcast networks bypassing their affiliates in this manner by
negotiating for, and if necessary enforcing via Commission rules,
contractual network non-duplication rights, which protect a broadcast
station's right to be the exclusive distributor of network programming
within a specified geographic zone. By contrast, in the world of online
video distribution, local affiliates lack a comparable regulatory
backstop. The ability of networks to achieve online distribution of
network programming in a local market, without the need for local
affiliates to consent, may give networks some additional leverage in
the network-affiliate relationship that did not exist in the pre-online
video world. What implications, if any, do developments related to the
growth of online video distribution have for the Dual Network Rule and
its underlying localism rationale?
62. As the Commission has previously noted, the Dual Network Rule
is intended to preserve the ability of local affiliates to advocate for
local interests in programming decisions. Would a Big Four network
merger reduce the ability of a network affiliate to use the
availability of other top, independently-owned networks as a bargaining
tool to influence programming decisions of its network, including the
affiliate's ability to engage in a dialogue with its network over the
suitability for local audiences of either the content or scheduling of
network programming? Have changes discussed above, including the growth
of online video or increased reverse compensation and retransmission
consent fees, affected bargaining between networks and affiliates on
programming and scheduling?
63. Considering the longstanding existence of the Dual Network
Rule, has localism increased, decreased, or remained roughly the same
over time? Are there recent examples where local affiliates have
influenced network programming to better serve local needs? Are there
other metrics by which we can assess the effect of the Dual Network
Rule on localism? Have other changes affected the network/affiliate
relationship, such that the Commission would need to adjust assumptions
made in previous reviews of the Dual Network Rule? For instance, has
the growth over the last two decades of station groups not owned and
operated by networks changed the dynamic between networks and their
affiliates? Do recent changes affecting the network-affiliate
relationship suggest that the Dual Network Rule should be modified,
rather than being retained or eliminated, to promote localism? If so,
what modifications should we make that would better promote localism?
64. Minority and Female Ownership. The Commission concluded in the
2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Order that, given the Dual Network Rule's
unique focus on mergers involving the Big Four networks rather than
ownership limits in local markets, the rule would not be expected to
have any meaningful impact on minority and female ownership levels. The
Commission seeks comment on whether and how market or other changes
since its last media ownership review may have affected this
conclusion. The Commission also seeks comment on how retaining,
modifying or eliminating the Dual Network Rule would affect broadcast
television ownership and entry by minority and female owners, if at
all. Finally, the Commission seeks comment on how retaining or
modifying the Dual Network Rule might affect broadcast television
ownership and entry by small business owners, if at all.
65. Diversity Related Proposals. The NPRM also seeks comment on
three proposals for increasing media diversity advanced by MMTC in
prior proceedings. These three proposals were distilled from a larger
list based on guidance from the Third Circuit in its decisions and
Commission staff, and the Commission already has adopted two
[[Page 6752]]
additional proposals from this list. The three proposals the Commission
now considers are: (1) Extending cable procurement requirements to
broadcasters; (2) developing a model for market based tradable
``diversity credits'' to serve as an alternative method for adopting
ownership limits; and (3) adopting formulas aimed at creating media
ownership limits that promote diversity.
66. Extending Cable Procurement Regulation. The 1992 Cable Act
states that a cable system must: ``[e]ncourage minority and female
entrepreneurs to conduct business with all parts of its operation.''
Sec. 76.75(e) of the Commission's rules explains that this requirement
may be met by, for example, recruiting as wide as possible a pool of
qualified entrepreneurs from sources such as employee referrals,
community groups, contractors, associations, and other sources likely
to be representative of minority and female interests. To help
determine whether this requirement can be applied to broadcasters, the
Commission seeks comment on the threshold issue of whether, because
Commission cable procurement authority flows directly from the 1992
Cable Act, it has authority to adopt a procurement requirement for
broadcasters. The Communications Act imposes equal employment
opportunity obligations on broadcasters, but no procurement
requirements. Does this difference between the two statutes reflect any
limitation on the Commission's otherwise extensive Communications Act
Title III authority over broadcasters? The Commission seeks comment on
potential sources of Commission authority, including any ancillary
authority, to extend procurement regulations to the broadcast industry.
The Commission also seeks comment on whether, by specifically
identifying minority/female entrepreneurs, the proposal would classify
these entrepreneurs differently from others such as to trigger
heightened judicial scrutiny. If heightened scrutiny is triggered, how
would such a rule comport with the Commission's previous finding in the
2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Order that it lacked the evidence to
satisfy the heightened scrutiny needed to justify race- or gender-based
broadcast regulation? Would inclusion of any type of audit, review, or
enforcement mechanism pursuant to which the Commission considered
broadcasters' compliance with the requirement be problematic or
interpreted as tacitly encouraging broadcasters to favor certain
entrepreneurs to the detriment of others in a way that would trigger
heightened scrutiny?
67. If a broadcast procurement rule as proposed by MMTC would
trigger heightened judicial scrutiny, can any proposed rule be modified
to be race- and gender-neutral to avoid the potential legal impediments
raised by a race- and gender-conscious broadcast procurement rule? In
such a case, how would the requirement be stated? Would a race- and
gender-neutral broadcast procurement rule be as effective as a race-
and gender-conscious broadcast procurement rule?
68. The Commission also seeks comment on MMTC's assertion in the
2010/2014 Quadrennial Review that Sec. 76.75(e) ``has been a
springboard for the migration of minority and women entrepreneurs into
operating and ownership positions in the cable and satellite
industries[,]'' and has ``contributed mightily to the economic success
of scores of minority and women owned businesses engaged in banking,
broker/dealer services, construction, fiber and satellite dish
installation, programming, legal services, accounting, and much more.''
In deciding whether to adopt additional regulations or extend a
regulation to additional industries, it is important to assess the
likelihood that the regulation would have the desired effect of
increasing minority and female participation in the broadcast industry.
Consequently, the Commission seeks data on the degree to which Sec.
76.75(e) has promoted minority and women businesses and whether any
broader trends in the intervening two decades since enactment of the
cable procurement requirement have played a role in fostering greater
minority and female participation in the cable industry. In this
regard, we also seek comment on the relative benefits and costs of
extending Sec. 76.75(e) to the broadcast industry. How can the value
of these benefits and costs be measured?
69. The Commission also notes the significant differences between
the cable and broadcast industries and seeks comment on the
feasibility--and utility--of imposing a Sec. 76.75(e)-type requirement
on the broadcast industry. For example, unlike broadcasters, cable
providers must construct and continuously maintain and upgrade a
significant physical plant and therefore purchase goods and services on
a much larger scale than broadcasters. Over-the-air delivery of
broadcast radio and television does not require laying fiber or coaxial
cable to every home and, in most instances, deploying customer premise
equipment, necessitating regular purchase of equipment and material at
significant volume. Constructing and maintaining extensive cable
networks also requires employing and contracting for far more labor
than is required in the broadcast sector. Unlike broadcasters, cable
operators maintain a direct billing relationship with their customers,
offering more contracting opportunities--in the form of outsourced
billing or customer service functions--than the broadcast industry.
Accordingly, the Commission seeks input on the feasibility and utility
of imposing a cable procurement regulation on broadcasters.
70. Develop a Model for Market-Based Tradeable Diversity Credits.
In reply comments submitted in the 2002 Biennial Review, a group called
the Diversity and Competition Supporters (DCS) advanced several
initiatives that it asserted would foster diversity, including
tradeable ``diversity credits'' for the broadcast industry. While
diversity credits weren't well defined, the idea appears to involve
creating a system of credits tradable in a market-based system and
redeemable by a broadcaster buying additional stations to offset any
increased concentration resulting from a proposed transaction. DCS
offered diversity credits as a potential alternative to the test then
in use by the Commission requiring that, for a broadcaster to own two
stations in a market, eight independent voices must have remained in
the market post-transaction. DCS suggested that economists (presumably
both at the Commission and beyond) could explore the concept and stated
its hope ``that other parties will attempt to design a market-based
Diversity Credit program.'' In 2004, a member of the Transactional
Transparency Subcommittee of the FCC Advisory Committee on Diversity in
the Digital Age further developed the diversity credits concept,
suggesting credits linked to each broadcast license based on the extent
to which the licensee was ``socially and economically disadvantaged''
and that, if a transaction promoted diversity (e.g., the breakup of a
local ownership cluster or the sale of a station to a socially and
economically disadvantaged business), the Commission would award the
seller additional diversity credits ``commensurate with the extent to
which the transaction promotes diversity.'' Similarly, according to
this 2004 proposal, if a transaction reduced diversity (e.g., by
creating an ownership combination or growing an ownership cluster), the
Commission would require diversity credits from the buyer, commensurate
with the extent to the which the transaction reduced diversity.
[[Page 6753]]
Finally, according to the 2004 proposal, if a company seeking approval
of a transaction held insufficient diversity credits to gain approval,
the company would need to purchase diversity credits on a secondary
market from third-party companies. The proposal did not define either
``promoting'' or ``reducing'' diversity, or how the impact of a
transaction would be measured or quantified. MMTC continued to advocate
for tradable diversity credits in the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review,
asking the Commission to explore their feasibility by issuing a Notice
of Inquiry. Therefore, the Commission now seeks comment on whether and
how it should create a system of tradable diversity credits that would
foster ownership diversity in broadcasting.
71. The Commission first seeks comment on its authority to adopt a
tradeable diversity credit system within its structural broadcast
ownership rules or otherwise. While the Communications Act contains no
explicit authority to create or rely on such a program, when presenting
the idea, DCS asserted that the sections 303(f), (g), and (r) of the
Communications Act provided authority to implement tradable diversity
credits. Are the sections cited by DCS applicable to such credits?
72. Assuming it has the required authority, the Commission seeks
comment on the feasibility of relying on determinations about social
and economic disadvantage given its concerns, expressed in the 2010/
2014 Quadrennial Review Order, about relying on such determinations. As
proposed, the allocation of diversity credits was based on the extent
to which the licensee could be considered ``socially and economically
disadvantaged.'' How should the term ``socially and economically
disadvantaged'' business (SDB) be defined? The 2004 proposal stated
that, ``[m]inority status could be a factor in qualifying as an SDB if
the Commission finds through rulemaking that minorities, under certain
conditions, are socially and economically disadvantaged in the
broadcasting industry because of their race[,]'' but did not provide
any guidance about when an individual might or might not qualify on the
basis of race. In the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Order, the
Commission found that the record did not establish a basis for race-
conscious remedies and concluded that such measures were unlikely to
withstand review under the equal protection component of the
Constitution's due process clause. Thus, the Commission, unlike the
Small Business Administration (SBA), declined to adopt an SDB
eligibility standard that would have recognized the race and ethnicity
of applicants, or any other race- or gender-conscious measure. Given
the Commission's previous findings and conclusions, can it adopt a
diversity credit program that considers race or gender, or other
protected classes, in a manner that could withstand equal protection
review? Commenters advocating for such a program should explain in
detail, based on relevant judicial precedent and existing empirical
data, how circumstances have changed such that the Commission could now
overcome the significant evidentiary issues that it previously found
would need to be resolved to adopt race- or gender-based policies that
could withstand heightened judicial scrutiny.
73. If the socially and economically disadvantaged concept in the
2004 proposal was a precursor to the Overcoming Disadvantages
Preference (ODP) concept that MMTC has advanced in subsequent
Commission rulemaking proceedings, the Commission in the 2010/2014
Quadrennial Review FNPRM assessed the ODP concept and stated concerns
that the Commission lacks the resources needed to conduct the
individualized reviews central to ODP. The Commission has similar
concerns about the administrative and practical challenges of
developing, implementing and applying a diversity credits program. The
2004 proposal suggested that the program rely on ascribing a diversity
credits number to each broadcast license or possibly each licensee. Who
would make that allocation of diversity credits, and on what criteria
would the Commission or other arbiter determine the number of credits
to be awarded to each license or licensee?
74. Such a program also raises potentially complicated definitional
issues. How would the Commission define ``diversity'' in this context?
In the 2002 Biennial Review Order, the Commission described several
types of diversity, focusing on viewpoint diversity as the relevant
touchstone for purposes of the structural media ownership rules. Would
a diversity credit system have as its goal fostering viewpoint
diversity, ownership diversity, both forms of diversity, or some other
type of diversity?
75. Once diversity is defined, how would parties--or the
Commission--determine, qualitatively or quantitatively, whether a
transaction promotes or harms diversity? How would the degree to which
the transaction harms or benefits diversity be quantified, such that
the number of credits awarded for, or required before approval of, such
a transaction could be determined? For example, would the impact on
diversity vary depending on the size of the market, the number of
operators therein, or the characteristics of the stations involved in
the transaction? Would a requirement that parties remit to the
Commission a certain number of diversity credits to receive approval of
a transaction replace the Commission's existing structural broadcast
ownership rules, which are based primarily on other policy goals, such
as competition and localism? Or would compliance with the diversity
credit regime be an additional requirement before a transaction were
permitted?
76. Recognizing that diversity credits could be used as a form of
currency in the broadcast market, how could the Commission effectively
test such a scheme to ensure it would not lead to any unintended
consequences? Developing and implementing a system that ensures that
the award of diversity credits leads to the desired result--increasing
diverse ownership in the broadcast market--rather than inadvertently
skewing the market towards an unintended outcome, including greater
concentration or loss of localism and viewpoint diversity, would seem
to be a particular challenge. The Commission seeks comment on how to
address these issues.
77. Tipping Point Formula and Source Diversity Formula. In 2002,
MMTC proposed a ``tipping point formula'' for use in the local radio
market in lieu of the Commission's now-abandoned practice of
``flagging'' radio transactions that, after initial analysis based on
advertising revenue, approached a level of local concentration that
raised public interest concerns about preserving diversity and
competition. In 2003, DCS proposed a ``source diversity formula'' for
use in the broader media market that seemed to be an attempt to
quantify the benefit derived from increased viewpoint diversity. As
with diversity credits, the Communications Act provides no explicit
authority to adopt or apply these formulas, and the Commission seeks
comment on possible sources of such statutory authority. Moreover,
because MMTC and DCS have provided little update to the formulas since
proposing them, the Commission seeks input generally on their relevance
in today's marketplace. The formulas also raise administrative and
practical concerns on which the Commission seeks comment, as discussed
below.
[[Page 6754]]
78. MMTC's tipping point formula attempted to determine when a
proposed transaction would create an entity that could control so much
advertising revenue that ``well run independents'' could not survive or
offer ``meaningful local service'' (all undefined). The formula's
asserted goal was to assess how much ``revenue'' an ``independent''
would need on average to survive in a given market, with this number
then being multiplied by the number of ``independents'' in that market.
Because the Commission's abandoned flagging approach relied on
advertising revenues, the term ``revenue'' in MMTC's tipping point
formula appears also to refer to advertising revenue. MMTC essentially
suggests that the Commission should bar any transaction that would
reduce the revenue available to support independent operators in a
market to an amount below what could sustain those operators. Stated
differently, a broadcaster would not be permitted to acquire competing
stations in a market if the purchase would create revenue so great as
to leave insufficient revenue for the independents in the market. MMTC
provided the following variables as inputs for its formula, as well as
the formula shown below:
MR: Market revenue.
MR1: Amount of market revenue drawn by largest platform.
MR2: Amount of market revenue drawn by second largest platform.
IN: Number of independent stations in the market.
SU: Minimum fixed cost for an independent station to stay on the
air.
VFSU: Variability Factor for Survival Operations, reflecting the
average amount of revenues per independent station that must be
available in the market, collectively, to take account of variations
among the independent stations and thereby ensure that well-run weak
independents stay on the air.
LS: Minimum additional cost, beyond SU, for an independent
station to offer a meaningful local service.
VFLS: Variability Factor for Local Service reflecting the
average amount of revenue per independent station that must be
available in the market, collectively, to take account of variations
among the independent stations and thereby ensure that well-run weak
independents remain viable.
LSTP: Local Service Tipping Point, i.e., the point at which, if
the top two station groups control more revenue, independents will
begin to lose their ability to offer meaningful local service.
SUTP: Survival Tipping Point, i.e., the point at which, if the
top two station groups control more revenue, independents will be
unable to meet their fixed operating costs and must, therefore, sell
out or go dark.
Based on these inputs, according to MMTC, the Local Service Tipping
Point is the point at which: IN (SU + VFSU + LS + VFLS) = MR-(MR1 +
MR2), and the Survival Tipping point is the point at which: IN (SU +
VFSU) = MR-(MR1 + MR2). In presenting these variables, MMTC noted that
``[t]he cost of maintaining a station on the air varies somewhat
depending on local market factors[,]'' that such regional or local
differences ``can be designed into a formula by indexing a market's
cost of living relative to the national average[,]'' and that such
issues could be addressed in a negotiated rulemaking involving all
interested parties.
79. We seek comment on the various terms used in the formula. For
example, how should the terms ``independent'' and ``platform'' be
defined in the context of today's radio marketplace? How should the
terms ``well-run independent'' and ``well-run weak independent'' be
defined? What objective criteria can we apply to distinguish between a
``well-run independent'' and a ``well-run weak independent'' to ensure
that use of a tipping point formula does not prop up stations that are
either poorly managed or simply not airing programming that responds to
the community's interests? What is meant by ``meaningful local
service''? We also seek comment on whether any determinations about how
well a station is run or the concept of ``meaningful local service''
might create First Amendment concerns.
80. MMTC's formula appears to rely on advertising revenues. If so,
how would the Commission and potential applicants obtain reliable
advertising revenue for all radio stations? If another type of revenue
is more appropriate, what data would the Commission rely on to obtain
information about this other revenue? How should the concept of ``fixed
operating costs'' be quantified? How should the Commission account for
local and regional cost differences?
81. Finally, the Commission seeks comment on what seems to be the
fundamental premise behind MMTC's tipping point formula: that retaining
independents (however that term is defined) in a market maintains
diversity (however that term is defined). We also invite commenters to
address any other issues that they believe are raised by the tipping
point formula proposal.
82. DCS submitted its source diversity formula in response to a
challenge from then-Chairman Powell to derive an ``HHI [Herfindahl-
Hirschman Index used to measure market concentration] for Diversity.''
The formula appears to seek to measure the level of consumer welfare
derived from viewpoint diversity in the radio and television broadcast
market, and DCS suggested it could be a ``thermometer'' to determine
whether ``a national or local market manifest[s] strong diversity,
moderate diversity, or slight diversity.'' DCS proposed that the
Commission conduct a negotiated rulemaking to determine what
significance to accord to various ``temperature readings'' on this
thermometer, i.e., what temperatures would reflect ``poor health,'' or
``strong health.'' DCS appeared to suggest that the source diversity
formula could be used in lieu of the Commission's now-repealed ``eight
voices'' test.
83. DCS depicted the source diversity formula as shown below with
the following variables: X = consumer welfare derived from viewpoint
diversity; p = a program consumed from a particular source; g = the
number of programs from a particular source that are available for
consumption; C = the number of consumers consuming a particular
program; T = consumers' mean media consumption time devoted to the
absorption of viewpoints in a particular program; Z = consumers' mean
attentiveness to a particular program; m = a source (including all
outlets owned by that source); and n = number of differently owned
sources offering programs consumed. The formula as proposed was:
[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP28FE19.006
DCS acknowledged that the formula was imperfect and would need testing
and validation before deployment.
84. The formula raises several fundamental questions. Is the
formula sufficiently comprehensive for commenters to gauge without
additional explanation whether it can provide a meaningful assessment
of consumer welfare and viewpoint diversity in a particular market? Are
there terms used in the formula inputs that require definition prior to
any assessment of the formula's utility? For example, do terms such as
``source'' and ``program'' need to
[[Page 6755]]
be defined before analyzing the formula? Are there other terms that
need defining? How will the formula inputs be obtained? For example, we
seek comment on how to capture inputs such as ``consumers' mean
attentiveness to a particular program'' and ``consumers' mean media
consumption time devoted to the absorption of viewpoints in a
particular program.'' How should the Commission determine the level of
diversity to ascribe to various formula results (e.g., ``strong
diversity,'' ``moderate diversity,'' or ``slight diversity'')? Finally,
the Commission invites commenters to address any other issues that they
believe are raised by the source diversity formula.
85. Cost-Benefit Analysis. For the three structural media ownership
rules and all of the diversity-related proposals discussed above, the
Commission seeks comment on how to compare the benefits and costs
associated with retaining, modifying or eliminating the rule or
adopting the diversity-related proposal, with any proposed modification
to the proposal. Commenters supporting modification or elimination of
any rule or adoption of any proposal should explain the anticipated
economic impact of any proposed action and, where possible, quantify
benefits and costs of proposed actions and alternatives. Do the current
rules create benefits or costs for any segment of consumers? Do the
rules create benefits or costs for any segment of the industry that
should be counted as social benefits or costs rather than transfers
from one segment of the industry to another? How do the rules create
these benefits and costs, and what evidence supports this explanation?
How can the value of these benefits and costs be measured for parties
receiving them? What factors create uncertainty about the existence or
size of these benefits and costs, and how should the Commission's
economic analysis take these uncertainties into account?
86. How would elimination of any rules alter the benefits and
costs? What are the comparative benefits and costs of modifying any
rule rather than eliminating it entirely? For instance, would loosening
the current local television or local radio ownership restrictions, or
allowing certain of the Big Four networks and not others to merge lead
to any consumer benefits, such as increased choice, innovation, or
investment in programming? What amount of additional scale would be
required to realize such benefits? Would these benefits conflict with,
or come at a cost to, our traditional policy goals of competition,
viewpoint diversity or localism, and if so, how should we measure and
evaluate these tradeoffs? What are the comparative benefits and costs
of tightening the current restrictions? The Commission asks commenters
to support their claims about benefits and costs with relevant economic
theory and evidence, including empirical analysis and data.
Procedural Matters
87. Ex Parte Rules--Permit-But-Disclose. The proceeding that this
NPRM initiates shall be treated as a ``permit-but-disclose'' proceeding
in accordance with the Commission's ex parte rules. Persons making ex
parte presentations must file a copy of any written presentation or a
memorandum summarizing any oral presentation within two business days
after the presentation (unless a different deadline applicable to the
Sunshine period applies). Persons making oral ex parte presentations
are reminded that memoranda summarizing the presentation must: (1) List
all persons attending or otherwise participating in the meeting at
which the ex parte presentation was made; and (2) summarize all data
presented and arguments made during the presentation. If the
presentation consisted in whole or in part of the presentation of data
or arguments already reflected in the presenter's written comments,
memoranda or other filings in the proceeding, the presenter may provide
citations to such data or arguments in his or her prior comments,
memoranda, or other filings (specifying the relevant page and/or
paragraph numbers where such data or arguments can be found) in lieu of
summarizing them in the memorandum. Documents shown or given to
Commission staff during ex parte meetings are deemed to be written ex
parte presentations and must be filed consistent with Sec. 1.1206(b)
of the Commission's rules. In proceedings governed by Sec. 1.49(f) of
the Commission's rules, or for which the Commission has made available
a method of electronic filing, written ex parte presentations and
memoranda summarizing oral ex parte presentations, and all attachments
thereto, must be filed through the Commission's Electronic Comment
Filing System (ECFS) available for that proceeding, and must be filed
in their native format (e.g., .doc, .xml, .ppt, searchable .pdf).
Participants in this proceeding should familiarize themselves with the
Commission's ex parte rules.
88. Filing Requirements--Comments and Replies. Pursuant to
Sec. Sec. 1.415 and 1.419 of the Commission's rules, interested
parties may file comments and reply comments on or before the dates
indicated on the first page of this document. Comments may be filed
using ECFS.
Electronic Filers: Comments may be filed electronically
using the internet by accessing the ECFS: https://apps.fcc.gov/ecfs/.
Paper Filers: Parties who choose to file by paper must
file an original and one copy of each filing.
Filings can be sent by hand or messenger delivery, by commercial
overnight courier, or by first-class or overnight U.S. Postal Service
mail. All filings must be addressed to the Commission's Secretary,
Office of the Secretary, Federal Communications Commission.
All hand-delivered or messenger-delivered paper filings
for the Commission's Secretary must be delivered to FCC Headquarters at
445 12th St. SW, Room TW-A325, Washington, DC 20554. The filing hours
are 8:00 a.m. to 7:00 p.m. All hand deliveries must be held together
with rubber bands or fasteners. Any envelopes and boxes must be
disposed of before entering the building.
Commercial overnight mail (other than U.S. Postal Service
Express Mail and Priority Mail) must be sent to 9050 Junction Drive,
Annapolis Junction, MD 20701.
U.S. Postal Service first-class, Express, and Priority
mail must be addressed to 445 12th Street SW, Washington, DC 20554.
89. Initial Regulatory Flexibility Act Analysis. The Regulatory
Flexibility Act of 1980, as amended (RFA), requires that a regulatory
flexibility analysis be prepared for notice and comment rulemaking
proceedings, unless the agency certifies that ``the rule will not, if
promulgated, have a significant economic impact on a substantial number
of small entities.'' The RFA generally defines the term ``small
entity'' as having the same meaning as the terms ``small business,''
``small organization,'' and ``small governmental jurisdiction.'' In
addition, the term ``small business'' has the same meaning as the term
``small business concern'' under the Small Business Act. A ``small
business concern'' is one which: (1) Is independently owned and
operated; (2) is not dominant in its field of operation; and (3)
satisfies any additional criteria established by the Small Business
Administration (SBA).
90. Written public comments are requested on the IFRA and must be
filed in accordance with the same filing deadlines as comments on this
NPRM, with a distinct heading designating them as responses to the
IRFA. In
[[Page 6756]]
addition, a copy of this NPRM and the IRFA will be sent to the Chief
Counsel for Advocacy of the SBA.
91. Paperwork Reduction Act. This NPRM seeks comment on whether the
Commission should adopt new or modified information collection
requirements. The Commission, as part of its continuing effort to
reduce paperwork burdens and pursuant to the Paperwork Reduction Act of
1995, invites the public and the Office of Management and Budget (OMB)
to comment on these information collection requirements. In addition,
pursuant to the Small Business Paperwork Relief Act of 2002, we seek
specific comment on how we might further reduce the information
collection burden for small business concerns with fewer than 25
employees.
92. People with Disabilities. To request materials in accessible
formats for people with disabilities (braille, large print, electronic
files, audio format), send an email to fcc504@fcc.gov or call the
Consumer and Governmental Affairs Bureau at 202-418-0530 (voice), 202-
418-0432 (tty).
93. Additional Information. For additional information on this
proceeding, please contact Brendan Holland of the Media Bureau,
Industry Analysis Division, Brendan.Holland@fcc.gov, (202) 418-2757.
Initial Regulatory Flexibility Analysis
94. Need for, and Objective of, the Proposed Rules. This NPRM
begins an examination of the Commission's media ownership rules and
possible changes to these rules. As discussed in the NPRM, the
Commission is required by statute to review its media ownership rules
every four years to determine whether they ``are necessary in the
public interest as the result of competition.'' Consistent with the
Communications Act, the Commission must examine its media ownership
rules and consider whether they continue to serve our public interest
goals of competition, viewpoint diversity and localism, or whether they
should be modified or eliminated. Specifically, the NPRM examines the
three remaining media ownership rules, the Local Radio Ownership Rule,
the Local Television Ownership Rule and the Dual Network Rule. In
addition, the NPRM seeks comment on several proposals that were
advanced in previous rulemakings and which the Commission indicated it
would examine further in the context of this review of its structural
ownership rules. These proposals, to extend cable procurement
requirements to broadcasters, develop a model for market-based,
tradeable ``diversity credits'' to serve as an alternative method for
adopting ownership limits, and adopt formulas aimed at creating media
ownership limits that promote diversity, are presented by their
proponents as initiatives that could further the Commission's diversity
goal. The Commission anticipates that these initiatives, if ultimately
adopted, might benefit small entities.
95. Legal Basis. The proposed action is authorized under sections
1, 2(a), 4(i), 303, 307, 309, and 310 of the Communications Act of
1934, as amended, and section 202(h) of the Telecommunications Act of
1996.
96. Description and Estimate of the Number of Small Entities to
which the Proposed Rules Apply. The RFA directs agencies to provide a
description of, and where feasible, an estimate of the number of small
entities that may be affected by the proposed rule revisions, if
adopted. The RFA generally defines the term ``small entity'' as having
the same meaning as the terms ``small business,'' ``small
organization,'' and ``small governmental jurisdiction.'' In addition,
the term ``small business'' has the same meaning as the term ``small
business concern'' under the Small Business Act (SBA). A small business
concern is one which: (1) Is independently owned and operated; (2) is
not dominant in its field of operation; and (3) satisfies any
additional criteria established by the SBA. Below, we provide a
description of such small entities, as well as an estimate of the
number of such small entities, where feasible.
97. Television Broadcasting. According to the U.S. Census Bureau
2017 NAICS Definitions, this U.S. Economic Census category ``comprises
establishments primarily engaged in broadcasting images together with
sound.'' These establishments operate television broadcast studios and
facilities for the programming and transmission of programs to the
public. These establishments also produce or transmit visual
programming to affiliated broadcast television stations, which in turn
broadcast the programs to the public on a predetermined schedule.
Programming may originate in their own studio, from an affiliated
network, or from external sources. The SBA has created the following
small business size standard for such businesses: those having $38.5
million or less in annual receipts. The 2012 Economic Census reports
that 751 firms in this category operated in that year. Of that number,
656 had annual receipts of $25 million or less, 25 had annual receipts
between $25 million and $49,999,999 and 70 had annual receipts of $50
million or more. Based on this data, the Commission estimates that the
majority of commercial television broadcast stations are small entities
under the applicable size standard.
98. Additionally, the Commission has estimated the number of
licensed commercial television stations to be 1,349. Of this total,
1,248 stations (or about 92.5 percent) had revenues of $38.5 million or
less, according to Commission staff review of the BIA Kelsey Inc. Media
Access Pro Television Database (BIA) in November 2018, and therefore
these stations qualify as small entities under the SBA definition.
99. Radio Broadcasting. This U.S. Economic Census category
``comprises establishments primarily engaged in broadcasting aural
programs by radio to the public.'' Programming may originate in their
own studio, from an affiliated network, or from external sources. The
SBA has created the following small business size standard for such
businesses: those having $38.5 million or less in annual receipts.
Economic Census data for 2012 show that 2,849 firms in this category
operated in that year. Of that number, 2,806 operated with annual
receipts of less than $25 million per year, 17 with annual receipts
between $25 million and $49,999,999 and 26 with annual receipts of $50
million or more. Based on this data, we estimate that the majority of
commercial radio broadcast stations were small under the applicable SBA
size standard.
100. Apart from the U.S. Economic Census, the Commission has
estimated the number of licensed commercial AM radio stations to be
4,426 stations and the number of commercial FM radio stations to be
6,737, for a total number of 11,364. Of this total, 11,355 stations (or
99.9 percent) had revenues of $38.5 million or less, according to
Commission staff review of the BIA Kelsey Inc. Media Access Pro
Television Database (BIA) in November 2018, and therefore these
stations qualify as small entities under the SBA definition.
101. In assessing whether a business concern qualifies as small
under the above definition, business (control) affiliations must be
included. Our estimate, therefore, likely overstates the number of
small entities that might be affected by our action because the revenue
figure on which it is based does not include or aggregate revenues from
affiliated companies. In addition, an element of the definition of
``small business'' is that the entity not be dominant in its field of
operation. We are unable at this time to define or quantify the
criteria that would establish whether a specific radio or
[[Page 6757]]
television station is dominant in its field of operation. Accordingly,
the estimate of small businesses to which the proposed rules may apply
does not exclude any radio or television station from the definition of
small business on this basis and is therefore possibly over-inclusive.
102. Description of Projected Reporting, Recordkeeping and other
Compliance Requirements. The proposals, if ultimately adopted, would
require modification of several Commission forms and their
instructions: (1) FCC Form 301, Application for Construction Permit for
Commercial Broadcast Station; (2) FCC Form 314, Application for Consent
to Assignment of Broadcast Station Construction Permit or License; and
(3) FCC Form 315, Application for Consent to Transfer Control of
Corporation Holding Broadcast Station Construction Permit or License.
The Commission also would modify, as necessary, other forms that
include in their instructions the media ownership rules or citations to
media ownership proceedings, including Form 303-S, Application for
Renewal License for AM, FM, TV, Translator, or LPTV Station and Form
323, Ownership Report for Commercial Broadcast Station. The impact of
these changes will be the same on all entities, and we do not
anticipate that compliance will require the expenditure of any
additional resources or place additional burdens on small businesses.
103. Steps Taken to Minimize Significant Economic Impact on Small
Entities, and Significant--Alternatives Considered. The RFA requires an
agency to describe any significant alternatives that it has considered
in reaching its proposed approach, which may include the following four
alternatives (among others): (1) The establishment of differing
compliance or reporting requirements or timetables that take into
account the resources available to small entities; (2) the
clarification, consolidation, or simplification of compliance or
reporting requirements under the rule for small entities; (3) the use
of performance, rather than design, standards; and (4) an exemption
from coverage of the rule, or any part thereof, for small entities.
104. The NPRM begins a statutorily mandated examination of whether
three remaining media ownership rules remain in the public interest as
a result of competition and promote the Commission's longstanding
policy goals of competition, viewpoint diversity and localism. The NPRM
acknowledges new technologies and changed marketplace conditions that
affect whether the rules remain in the public interest considering
competition and the need to allow broadcasters, including small
entities, to achieve the economies of scale and scope necessary to
continue to compete in a changed marketplace. The NPRM considers
measures designed to minimize the economic impact of any changes to
these rules on firms generally, as well as initiatives designed to
promote broadcast ownership opportunities among a diverse group of
owners, including small entities. The NPRM also invites comment on the
effects of any rule changes on different types of broadcasters (e.g.,
independent or network-affiliated), the benefits and costs associated
with any proposals, and any potential to have significant impact on
small entities.
105. The NPRM proposes no new reporting requirements, performance
standards or other compliance obligations, although, as discussed
above, it may modify, as necessary, certain existing reporting forms
should it adopt any changes to its media ownership rules. Should the
Commission ultimately adopt changes to its media ownership rules that
could increase requirements or compliance burdens for small entities,
it will determine whether possible exemptions, waiver opportunities,
extended compliance deadlines or other measures would mitigate any
potential impact on small entities.
106. Federal Rules that May Duplicate, Overlap or Conflict with the
Proposed Rules. None.
Ordering Clauses
107. Accordingly, it is ordered that, pursuant to the authority
contained in sections 1, 2(a), 4(i), 257, 303, 307, 309, 310, and 403
of the Communications Act of 1934, as amended, and section 202(h) of
the Telecommunications Act of 1996, this Notice of Proposed Rulemaking
is adopted.
108. It is further ordered, pursuant to applicable procedures set
forth in Sec. Sec. 1.415 and 1.419 of the Commission's rules,
interested parties may file comments on the NPRM in MB Docket No. 18-
349 on or before sixty (60) days after publication in the Federal
Register and reply comments on or before ninety (90) days after
publication in the Federal Register.
109. It is furthered ordered that the Commission's Consumer and
Governmental Affairs Bureau, Reference Information Center, shall send a
copy of this NPRM, including the IRFA, to the Chief Counsel for
Advocacy of the Small Business Administration.
Federal Communications Commission.
Katura Jackson,
Federal Register Liaison Officer, Office of the Secretary.
[FR Doc. 2019-03278 Filed 2-27-19; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6712-01-P