Regulation of Business Data Services for Rate-of-Return Local Exchange Carriers; Business Data Services in an internet Protocol Environment; Special Access for Price Cap Local Exchange Carriers, 67098-67123 [2018-27528]
Download as PDF
67098
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 248 / Friday, December 28, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
amozie on DSK3GDR082PROD with RULES
Dated: December 21, 2018.
Tim Noelker,
General Counsel.
regulation voluntarily. Price cap
regulation was designed to ‘‘reward
companies that became more productive
and efficient, while ensuring that
[FR Doc. 2018–28266 Filed 12–27–18; 8:45 am]
productivity and efficiency gains are
BILLING CODE 6050–28–P
shared with ratepayers.’’ Through a
series of subsequent decisions, the
Commission allowed other carriers to
FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS
convert voluntarily from rate-of-return
COMMISSION
to price cap regulation.
2. Since then, the Commission has
47 CFR Parts 1, 32, 51, 61, and 69
taken additional steps to transition
[WC Docket Nos. 17–144, 16–143, 05–25;
certain services and revenues of rate-ofFCC 18–146]
return carriers from rate-of-return
regulation to other more efficient forms
Regulation of Business Data Services
of regulation. In 2011, as part of
for Rate-of-Return Local Exchange
comprehensive universal service and
Carriers; Business Data Services in an intercarrier compensation reform, the
internet Protocol Environment; Special Commission imposed rate caps on rateAccess for Price Cap Local Exchange
of-return carriers’ switched access
Carriers
services, removing those services from
the obligations that accompany
AGENCY: Federal Communications
traditional rate-or-return regulation. In
Commission.
the USF/ICC Transformation Order, 76
ACTION: Final rule.
FR 73830, November 29, 2011, the
SUMMARY: The Commission continues its Commission also changed its method for
calculating high-cost universal service
efforts to modernize its rules governing
support received by rate-of-return
the pricing of business data services
(BDS) by allowing rate-of-return carriers affiliates of price cap carriers.
Specifically, the Commission began to
to voluntarily elect to transition their
treat rate-of-return operating companies
BDS offerings out of rate-of-return
affiliated with price-cap holding
regulation to a lighter-touch regulatory
companies as price cap LECs for the
framework. This action is intended to
purposes of the Connect America Fund
promote competition and reduce costly
(CAF) Phase I distribution mechanism.
regulatory burdens which no longer
As a result, rate-of-return carriers
serve the public interest. Under this
affiliated with price-cap companies now
new framework, rate-of-return carriers
would be incentivized to use the savings receive the same type of fixed universal
service support that their price cap
realized from the regulatory relief to
affiliates receive.
improve existing networks and service.
3. Two years ago, the Commission
DATES: The amendments contained in
gave rate-of-return carriers the option of
this final rule shall become effective
receiving forward looking, model-based
February 26, 2019.
universal service support based on the
ADDRESSES: Federal Communications
Alternative Connect America Cost
Commission, 445 12th Street SW,
Model (A–CAM), which more than 200
Washington, DC 20554.
carriers opted to receive (A–CAM
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
carriers). The Commission observed that
Justin Faulb, Pricing Policy Division of
‘‘the carriers that choose to take the
the Wireline Competition Bureau at
voluntary path to the model are electing
202–418–1540 or by email at
incentive regulation for common line
Justin.Faulb@fcc.gov.
offerings.’’ Consequently, for A–CAM
carriers, only their BDS offerings are
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: This is a
currently subject to rate-of-return
summary of the Commission’s Report
and Order, released October 24, 2018. A regulation.
4. In 2016, the Commission also
full-text version may be obtained at the
adopted the Alaska Plan Order, 81 FR
following internet address: https://
69696, October 7, 2016, which allowed
www.fcc.gov/document/fcc-spursAlaskan rate-of-return carriers to elect
competition-rural-business-datafixed universal service support on a
services-0.
state-wide basis for a defined term in
I. Background
exchange for committing to deployment
1. In 1990, the Commission began the obligations. Specifically, the
Commission provided a one-time
process of encouraging carriers to move
opportunity for Alaskan rate-of-return
from rate-of-return to incentive
carriers to elect to receive universal
regulation by adopting price cap rules
service support frozen at adjusted 2011
governing the largest incumbent LECs’
levels for a 10-year term in exchange for
interstate access charges and allowing
other incumbent LECs to elect price cap meeting individualized performance
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:02 Dec 27, 2018
Jkt 247001
PO 00000
Frm 00066
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
benchmarks to offer voice and
broadband services. Subsequently, in
2016, the Wireline Competition Bureau
(Bureau) authorized 13 Alaskan rate-ofreturn carriers to receive universal
service support under the Alaska Plan
(Alaska Plan carriers). Similar to A–
CAM carriers, Alaska Plan carriers
receive fixed universal service support
that is not based on current cost, and
only file cost studies for purposes of
their BDS offerings.
5. In addition to encouraging carriers
to migrate from cost-based to incentive
regulation, over time the Commission
has reduced ex ante pricing regulation
in favor of relying on competition to the
extent possible. In 1999, the
Commission granted pricing flexibility
to price cap carriers that provided
service in areas where carriers could
demonstrate threshold levels of
deployment by competitive providers.
Pricing flexibility allowed eligible
carriers to offer BDS using contract
tariffs, volume and term discounts and,
in markets that demonstrated higher
levels of competition, at unregulated
rates. Beginning in 2007, the
Commission granted forbearance from
dominant carrier regulation, including
tariffing and pricing regulation, to a
number of price cap incumbent LECs for
their newer packet-based broadband
services. These forbearance orders
concluded that forbearance from
dominant carrier regulation was
warranted given the existence of
competition for these newer services,
which ensured that rates and practices
for these services remained just and
reasonable, adequately protected
consumers, and was in the public
interest.
6. In 2017, the Commission adjusted
BDS pricing regulation to the reality of
a dynamically competitive BDS market
in areas where incumbent LECs were
subject to price cap regulation. The
Commission premised its reductions in
ex ante pricing regulation in part on a
substantial data collection and in part
on its predictive judgment that dynamic
and growing competition in the BDS
market, driven increasingly by the
emergence of cable competition, would
allow reliance on competition rather
than regulation to ensure rates remain
just and reasonable. The BDS Order, 82
FR 25660, June 2, 2017, represented yet
another step in the process of reducing
dominant carrier regulation in response
to the growth of competition. In that
order, the Commission found that
reducing government intervention and
allowing market forces to continue
working would further spur entry,
innovation, and competition in BDS
markets served by price cap carriers.
E:\FR\FM\28DER1.SGM
28DER1
amozie on DSK3GDR082PROD with RULES
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 248 / Friday, December 28, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
The Commission applied ex ante pricing
regulation ‘‘only where competition is
expected to materially fail to ensure just
and reasonable rates’’ and stated its
preference to rely ‘‘on competition
rather than regulation, wherever
purchasers can realistically turn to a
supplier beyond the incumbent LEC.’’
Based on the record before it, the
Commission found that, on balance,
competition was sufficient to ensure just
and reasonable rates for packet-based
business data services, TDM transport
services, and higher bandwidth (i.e.,
above a DS3-level) TDM services
(including OCn services) in the absence
of ex ante pricing regulation in areas
served by price cap carriers. It also
adopted a competitive market test for
lower bandwidth TDM end user channel
terminations (i.e., DS3-level and lower)
in price cap areas and refrained from ex
ante pricing regulation of those services
in areas deemed competitive by that
test.
7. Recently, the Eighth Circuit Court
of Appeals upheld all aspects of the BDS
Order save the portions of the order
affecting price cap carriers’ TDM
transport service, which it vacated and
remanded on notice grounds—namely
that the Commission had not provided
sufficient notice that it might relieve
those services of ex ante pricing
regulation.
8. After the Commission adopted
changes to its rules governing price cap
carriers’ BDS offerings, ITTA and
USTelecom (together, Petitioners) filed a
petition seeking the same regulatory
treatment of BDS offerings for rate-ofreturn carriers receiving fixed support
as that the Commission had recently
adopted for price cap carriers (Joint
Petition). According to Petitioners, rateof-return regulation deters investment in
networks and harms competition.
Petitioners argue that the inflexibility of
rate-of-return regulation makes it
difficult to justify and fund upgrades to
their rural networks. They point out that
for rate-of-return carriers, ‘‘the need to
perform annual cost studies now applies
only with respect to BDS.’’ As a result,
they argue that the expense associated
with conducting cost studies and
complying with other rate-of-return
expenses are difficult to recover and
burden rate-of-return carriers receiving
fixed support but not their competitors.
The Bureau sought and received
comment on the Joint Petition.
9. Upon review of the record received
in response to the Joint Petition, earlier
this year, the Commission released a
notice of proposed rulemaking (NPRM),
83 FR 22923, May 17, 2018, proposing
to allow A–CAM and other rate-ofreturn carriers that receive fixed
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:02 Dec 27, 2018
Jkt 247001
universal service support to voluntarily
migrate their lower speed TDM-based
BDS offerings to incentive regulation.
The Commission also sought comment
on adopting a competitive market test to
determine when the market for lower
speed TDM-based BDS offerings offered
by rate-of-return carriers that receive
fixed support are sufficiently
competitive to justify eliminating ex
ante pricing regulation of such offerings.
Additionally, the NPRM sought
comment on eliminating ex ante pricing
regulation for such carriers’ packetbased and higher speed TDM-based BDS
offerings nationwide, while maintaining
oversight authority through sections
201, 202, and 208 of the
Communications Act of 1934, as
amended (the Communications Act or
the Act) to ensure BDS rates and
practices remain just and reasonable.
II. An Administrable Framework for
Business Data Services Offered By Rateof-Return Carriers That Receive Fixed
Support
10. Upon review of the record, we
allow rate-of-return carriers receiving
fixed universal service support to
choose to migrate their BDS offerings to
a new, comprehensive, lighter-touch
regulatory framework that is better
aligned to the competitive realities of
the BDS markets they serve. The
framework we adopt includes voluntary
incentive regulation with pricing
flexibility for electing carriers’ lower
capacity (DS3 and below) TDM
transport and end user channel
termination services. We also adopt a
competitive market test for such
carriers’ lower capacity TDM end user
channel termination services to identify
competition by study area. In electing
carriers’ study areas that the competitive
market test deems competitive, we
eliminate ex ante pricing regulation for
lower capacity TDM end user channel
termination services. We also remove ex
ante pricing regulation from electing
carriers’ packet-based and higher
capacity (above a DS3 bandwidth level)
TDM services and grant forbearance
from tariffing requirements for those
services. To reduce the burden of legacy
rate-of-return regulation on electing
carriers, we also grant forbearance from
cost assignment and separations rules
and related reporting requirements,
because we determine that such action
is warranted by the non-cost-based
regulation that will apply to electing
carriers and the competitive
circumstances of their BDS markets.
11. We find that adopting the lightertouch incentive regulatory framework
proposed by the Commission for
electing carriers will remove
PO 00000
Frm 00067
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
67099
unnecessary regulatory burdens and
encourage competition. Based on the
record before us, we decline at this time
to relieve electing carriers’ lower
capacity TDM transport (at or below a
DS3-level) of ex ante pricing regulation
nationwide, as Petitioners sought.
Instead we allow electing carriers to
move their lower speed TDM transport
services to incentive regulation.
Additionally, we adopt a competitive
market test tailored to rate-of-return
carriers’ study areas, which will allow
us to properly evaluate competition in
the areas served by electing carriers and
remove ex ante pricing regulation for
end user channel terminations in areas
deemed competitive, instead of basing
our decision on the competitive
characteristics of areas served by price
cap carriers.
12. We decline to adopt Petitioners’
proposal to apply to electing carriers’
BDS offerings the regulatory framework
and the results of the price cap
competitive market test adopted in the
BDS Order for price cap carriers’ BDS
offerings. Petitioners argue that applying
the price cap BDS rules to electing rateof-return carriers would result in
regulatory parity that ‘‘would promote
competition and make the rules less
complex.’’ TDS Telecom asserts that
adopting a separate incentive regulatory
framework is unnecessary. The price
cap BDS rules, however, were based on
an analysis of BDS competition in areas
served by price cap carriers, consistent
with our obligation to ensure that the
rates charged by common carriers are
just and reasonable. The Commission
found sufficient evidence of
competition in these areas to discipline
pricing and therefore adopt a lighter
touch regulatory framework for these
carriers. That same history and record of
competition for BDS services does not
exist in the study areas served by rateof-return carriers that Petitioners seek to
have covered by price cap BDS
regulation. Thus, we find that adopting
a separate, albeit largely parallel,
regulatory framework for rate-of-return
carriers receiving fixed support will be
better suited to their circumstances.
A. Transitioning to a New Framework
13. Consistent with the Commission’s
proposal and the Joint Petition, we
allow all rate-of-return carriers receiving
fixed universal service support to
voluntarily elect to move their BDS
offerings out of rate-of-return regulation
to the new lighter touch framework we
adopt today. Carriers eligible to make
this election include A–CAM carriers,
rate-of-return carriers receiving fixed
support by virtue of being affiliated with
price cap carriers, Alaska Plan carriers,
E:\FR\FM\28DER1.SGM
28DER1
amozie on DSK3GDR082PROD with RULES
67100
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 248 / Friday, December 28, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
and rate-of-return carriers that accept
future offers of A–CAM support or
otherwise transition away from legacy
support mechanisms. The first three
types of carriers receive fixed or modelbased universal service support, rather
than receiving high-cost support based
on their costs, and therefore are
currently required to prepare cost
studies only for their BDS offerings.
Relieving these carriers of rate-of-return
regulation for their BDS will save them
the expense of preparing burdensome
cost studies only for those offerings.
14. Similarly, to the extent the
Commission provides future offers of A–
CAM support or otherwise transitions
carriers away from legacy support
mechanisms, carriers that receive such
support will only have to prepare cost
studies for purposes of their BDS
offerings. Therefore, if the Commission
announces future offers of A–CAM
support or otherwise transitions carriers
away from legacy support mechanisms,
the actions we take in this Order will
allow carriers eligible for or subject to
such transitions to elect the same lighter
touch regulatory framework we provide
for other rate-of-return carriers that
receive fixed support, and may provide
further incentives for rate-of-return
carriers to elect to receive non-legacy,
fixed or model-based support. This will
further the Commission’s longstanding
objective of providing universal service
support based on forward-looking
efficient costs as opposed to actual costs
that may be less efficient.
15. Consistent with Commission
precedent, we do not require all rate-ofreturn carriers receiving fixed support to
migrate their BDS offerings away from
rate-of-return regulation to the new
framework, but instead allow each
carrier to voluntarily make that
determination based on its
circumstances. When the Commission
adopted price cap regulation in 1990, it
made price cap regulation voluntary for
all but the largest incumbent LECs. At
that time, the Commission expressed
concern that assigning one productivity
factor on a mandatory basis to all LECs,
regardless of size, could prove unduly
burdensome for smaller and mid-sized
carriers that may have fewer
opportunities than larger companies to
achieve cost savings and efficiencies.
Commenters echoed those concerns in
this proceeding. By making the election
voluntary, we ensure that only carriers
that can achieve sufficient efficiencies
are likely to elect incentive regulation;
our new framework will not, therefore,
impose additional burdens on smaller
carriers that cannot achieve such
efficiencies.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:02 Dec 27, 2018
Jkt 247001
16. We also adopt the Commission’s
proposal to require electing carriers to
elect incentive regulation at the holding
company-level for study areas in all
states where that carrier receives fixed
support. Commenters do not oppose
requiring holding company-level
election. AT&T requests that the
Commission ‘‘require that any A–CAM
carrier that elects incentive regulation
have that election apply across all its
study areas’’ because this prevents
‘‘internal cost shifting among study
areas.’’ Holding company-level election
will maximize the regulatory
efficiencies achieved by incentive
regulation, including maximizing cost
savings from the elimination of cost
studies for all electing carriers. It is also
consistent with the Commission’s past
practices. For example, the Commission
gave rate-of-return carriers the
opportunity to elect between A–CAM
and legacy cost-based support at a statewide level. Likewise, the Commission
required Alaska Plan carriers to elect
fixed, frozen support on a state-wide
basis. Requiring rate-of-return carriers
receiving fixed support to elect
regulatory treatment at the holding
company-level is also consistent with
the underlying premise of price cap
regulation, which assumed a broad
representation of carrier operations to
provide a basis for establishing an
industry-wide productivity factor.
17. We provide eligible carriers with
two opportunities to elect to move their
BDS offerings out of rate-of-return
regulation—one to be effective as of July
1, 2019 and a second effective as of July
1, 2020—to encourage them to take
advantage without undue delay of the
benefits that will be realized by electing
carriers under the new framework and
to discourage potential gaming
opportunities. We provide two
opportunities to elect this new
regulatory framework, in recognition of
the fact that some carriers may not have
sufficient time to assess their options in
time for the July 1, 2019 effective date.
Providing a second opportunity to elect
incentive regulation will facilitate
carriers’ ability to assess incentive
regulation for their BDS and ultimately
enhance participation in the new
regulatory framework, which will
further reduce unnecessary regulatory
burdens and positively impact
competition in electing carriers’ BDS
markets.
18. Some commenters recommend
that we provide an ‘‘annual opportunity
to elect the new regime’’ based on
‘‘business strategy and compliance
measures.’’ Giving eligible carriers an
annual opportunity to elect incentive
regulation, however, would also give
PO 00000
Frm 00068
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
them an incentive to increase their
operating costs and rate base under rateof-return regulation in order to raise
rates prior to electing incentive
regulation, then realize additional
profits by cutting costs under incentive
regulation at the expense of ratepayers.
By providing only two opportunities to
elect to move to the new framework, we
discourage such gaming opportunities.
19. We prohibit electing carriers from
returning their study areas to rate-ofreturn regulation. One of the rationales
for the Commission’s ‘‘all-or-nothing’’
rules for price cap carriers is to prevent
carriers from potentially switching back
and forth between rate-of-return and
price cap regulation to take advantage of
uneven cycles of investment. We are
likewise concerned with potential
gaming opportunities for electing
carriers if they are allowed to switch
back and forth between rate-of-return
and incentive regulation. Electing
carriers could inflate their revenues by
opting-out of incentive regulation,
building a larger rate base under rate-ofreturn regulation in order to raise rates,
and then, returning to incentive
regulation or opting into price cap
regulation, thus reducing costs back to
an efficient level. These gaming
opportunities would distort carriers’
decisions to invest and frustrate the
public interest because ratepayers
would not see the benefit of capped and
decreased rates in the manner intended
under incentive regulation. Further, in
the 1990 Price Cap Order, 55 FR 42375,
October 19, 1990, the Commission
determined that for price cap regulation
to work effectively and for incentives to
develop and influence carrier behavior
and earnings, an electing carrier must
make a permanent commitment. We
similarly find, that for incentive
regulation to work properly, the election
must be permanent. Accordingly, a
carrier’s voluntary election of incentive
regulation will be irrevocable.
20. AT&T requests that the
‘‘Commission decline to waive the ‘allor-nothing’ rule for these carriers and
require that any A–CAM carrier that
elects incentive regulation have that
election apply across all its study areas
and, even more critically, across all of
its interstate services within a study
area.’’ The all-or-nothing rule AT&T
cites, however, applies to price cap
carriers, not to rate-of-return carriers
that elect incentive regulation. While
the incentive regulation rules we adopt
for electing carriers impose price caps
on some of the BDS services offered by
electing carriers, electing carriers do not
become price cap carriers by virtue of
their election; therefore the all-or-
E:\FR\FM\28DER1.SGM
28DER1
amozie on DSK3GDR082PROD with RULES
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 248 / Friday, December 28, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
nothing rule is simply not applicable
here.
21. We allow electing carriers’
switched access services to remain
subject to the multi-year transition
provided for rate-of-return carriers in
the USF/ICC Transformation Order. We
therefore decline to adopt AT&T’s
recommendation that electing carriers
be required to convert all their services
to price cap regulation, including their
switched access services, which—
compared to price-cap carriers’
switched access services—benefit from a
longer transition to bill-and-keep and no
phase-out of Connect America Fund
Intercarrier Compensation replacement
support.
22. According to AT&T ‘‘[w]hile
different transitions for price cap
carriers and rate-of-return carriers may
have made sense in 2011, those
distinctions should not unfairly benefit
carriers’’ electing incentive regulation
and could lead to cost-shifting between
types of services. We disagree with
AT&T’s assertion that electing carriers
will ‘‘unfairly benefit’’ from our
decision not to convert all of their
offerings to incentive regulation. The
Commission adopted different
intercarrier compensation transitions in
the context of a complex rulemaking
that were the result of a careful analysis
of a variety of factors and policy
considerations, including the
differential impact of universal service
and intercarrier compensation reform on
price cap as compared to rate-of-return
carriers. As TDS Telecom explains, in
the intervening seven years, carriers
have relied on those transitions to plan
their businesses and make investments.
Changing those transitions at this point
would disrupt these settled expectations
and potentially undermine, rather than
encourage, investment and innovation
in electing carriers’ BDS markets. We
also find AT&T’s concerns about costshifting unfounded because switched
access rates were capped and therefore
removed from cost-based regulation in
2011 by the USF/ICC Transformation
Order, eliminating the incentive for
inappropriate cost shifting.
23. Following the same logic, we
decline to adopt AT&T’s proposal that
we require electing carriers to exit the
National Exchange Carrier Association
(NECA) tariff pool for their ‘‘switched
and special access services to avoid
additional complexities in the annual
tariff review process and to avoid
potential gaming.’’ As Petitioners argue,
AT&T ‘‘fails to explain how any cost
shifting would be useful given the
switched access rules [that cap rates].’’
Moreover, the scrutiny inherent in the
part 61 tariff review process helps
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:02 Dec 27, 2018
Jkt 247001
reduce the risk of cost-shifting or other
gaming by pool participants. We do,
however, require electing carriers
currently participating in the NECA
traffic-sensitive tariff pool for their BDS
or special access service offerings to
remove their BDS and special access
offerings from the pool since those
services will be subject to incentive
regulation.
24. We find that the lighter touch
regulatory framework we adopt provides
electing carriers the right balance of
relief from the burdensome aspects of
rate-of-return regulation and pricing
discipline. The efficiencies gained from
reducing regulatory burdens on electing
carriers, including the increased
flexibility to compete in the market, will
foster network investment and impose
downward pressure on prices. We also
find here, as we did in the BDS Order,
that ‘‘minimiz[ing] unnecessary
government intervention . . . allows
market forces to continue working to
spur entry, innovation, and
competition.’’
B. Applying Voluntary Incentive
Regulation to Electing Carriers’ Lower
Speed TDM Transport and End User
Channel Termination Services
25. In this section, we provide
direction on implementing the
voluntary incentive regulation we adopt
today for electing carriers’ lower
capacity (i.e., at or below a DS3-level)
TDM transport and end user channel
termination services as part of our
comprehensive lighter touch regulatory
framework for electing carriers’ BDS.
We treat electing carriers’ lower
capacity TDM transport and end user
channel terminations differently from
packet-based and higher speed TDMbased BDS offerings because the record
shows that packet-based offerings are
subject to competition that will ensure
just and reasonable rates for those
services. By contrast, the record shows
that demand for lower speed TDMbased transport and end user channel
terminations services is shrinking as
purchasers increasingly prefer higher
speed and packet-based services.
Recognizing that the market is
transitioning to new technologies, we
provide protections for lower speed
TDM-based transport and end user
channel termination services. Based on
the current record, we preserve ex ante
pricing regulation for lower speed TDMbased transport services and adopt a
competitive market test that will
preserve ex ante pricing regulation in
those study areas where we predict
there is a substantial likelihood that
competition will fail to ensure just and
reasonable rates for the lower capacity
PO 00000
Frm 00069
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
67101
TDM-based end user channel
termination services.
26. Rate-of-return carriers that make
this election will convert to incentive
regulation for their lower capacity TDM
transport and end user channel
termination services as well as other
generally lower capacity non-packetbased services that are commonly
considered special access services.
Specifically, among other matters, we
adopt a methodology for electing
carriers to set their initial rates, allow an
unfreeze of separations category
relationships for carriers that elected to
freeze them in 2001, adopt a
productivity factor and measure of
inflation to adjust rates, and grant
pricing flexibility to electing carriers for
their lower capacity TDM services.
1. Initial Rate Levels
27. First, we adopt the methodology
electing carriers must use to establish
rates for their lower capacity TDM
transport and end user channel
termination services pursuant to
incentive regulation. For rate-of-return
carriers that file their own tariffed rates,
we adopt the approach proposed in the
NPRM to set initial BDS rate levels
based on rates in effect on January 1,
2019 for carriers converting to incentive
regulation as of July 1, 2019 and on rates
in effect on January 1, 2020 for carriers
that elect incentive regulation effective
as of July 1, 2020. For rate-of-return
carriers participating in the NECA
traffic-sensitive tariff pool that elect
incentive regulation effective July 1,
2019, we adopt the approach proposed
in the NPRM for members exiting the
pool to set their initial BDS rate levels
by adjusting NECA pool rates in effect
on January 1, 2019 by a net contribution
or net recipient factor. Carriers electing
incentive regulation as of July 1, 2020
must set their initial BDS rate levels by
adjusting NECA pool rates in effect on
January 1, 2020. Electing carriers will
then adjust their rates using a
methodology that is consistent with the
price cap formulas in §§ 61.45 to 61.47
of our rules, by applying the
productivity factor (X-factor), inflation
factor (Gross Domestic Product-Price
Index (GDP–PI)), and any required
exogenous cost changes. Carriers may
adjust these rates to reflect the pricing
flexibility permitted by the pricing
bands in the Special Access category.
28. Under rate-of-return regulation,
incumbent LECs are permitted to
recover through tariffed rates their
revenue requirement, which is equal to
their regulated operating costs plus a
prescribed rate of return on their
regulated rate base. Rate-of-return
carriers set rates at levels that when
E:\FR\FM\28DER1.SGM
28DER1
amozie on DSK3GDR082PROD with RULES
67102
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 248 / Friday, December 28, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
multiplied by demand will yield
revenues equal to their revenue
requirement, and are targeted to earn the
Commission’s prescribed rate of return.
Rate-of-return carriers establish rates for
BDS offerings either by filing their own
interstate access tariffs and cost support
pursuant to § 61.38 or § 61.39 of our
rules or, for most rate-of-return carriers,
by participating in the NECA trafficsensitive tariff and traffic-sensitive pool.
NECA sets the BDS rates in the trafficsensitive tariff based on projected
aggregate costs (or average schedule
settlements) and demand of all pool
members, which are targeted to earn the
authorized rate of return for NECA pool
members.
29. When the Commission launched
price cap regulation in 1990, it found
that interstate access rates as they
existed on July 1, 1990, six months prior
to the date price caps went into effect
on January 1, 1991, were the most
reasonable basis from which to set
initial rate levels under price cap
regulation. In other words, those rates
created the starting point for the
indexing of rates under price cap
regulation—setting their price cap
index, actual price index and service
band index at a value of 100. The price
cap index is adjusted by the
productivity offset (X-factor) and
inflation (GDP–PI) for the first year, and
each year thereafter. The Commission
reasoned that interstate rates that
existed on July 1, 1990 ‘‘while perhaps
not perfect, in general represent the best
that rate-of-return regulation can
produce.’’
30. Beginning with the Windstream
Order, the Commission granted several
waivers allowing price cap carriers to
convert their rate-of-return study areas
to price cap regulation. Carriers were,
among other things, required to
establish initial price cap indexes using
the rates in effect on January 1 of the
conversion year, six months prior to the
July 1 effective date of conversion, the
demand from the preceding year, and
required to target their rates using the Xfactor in effect at that time. In the 2012
Average Schedule Conversion Order, the
Commission permitted several rate-ofreturn carriers to, among other things,
withdraw their average schedule study
areas from the NECA pool and convert
them to price cap regulation. In that
order, the Commission approved a
methodology for establishing initial
price cap rates using existing NECA
pool tariffed rates adjusted to reflect the
extent to which the exiting study areas
were either a net contributor to, or a net
recipient from, the NECA pool.
31. Carriers Currently Filing Their
Own Tariffs. Consistent with past
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:02 Dec 27, 2018
Jkt 247001
practice, we adopt the proposal in the
NPRM for carriers that currently file
their own tariffs to use existing tariffed
rates to set their initial BDS rates under
incentive regulation. Carriers first will
set their price cap indexes based on
their tariffed interstate special access
rates in effect on January 1, 2019, or
based on those rates in effect on January
1, 2020 for carriers electing to convert
to incentive regulation effective July 1,
2020. The price cap indexes (i.e., the
price cap index, actual price index, and
service band index) will be assigned
values of 100 as starting points, which
correspond to rate levels in effect on
January 1, 2019 or on January 1, 2020,
as applicable. Carriers then will adjust
the price cap index and the pricing band
limits for each service category or
subcategory consistent with §§ 61.45
through 61.47 of our rules, by applying
the X-factor (2.0%), inflation factor
(GDP–PI), and any required exogenous
cost changes. Carriers, next, will set
rates so that the actual price index,
calculated pursuant to § 61.46, does not
exceed the price cap index, and the
service band indexes for each service
category or subcategory, calculated
pursuant to § 61.47, do not exceed the
pricing band limits for each category or
subcategory, for the first year of
incentive regulation and each year
thereafter.
32. Carriers Participating in NECA
Pool. We also adopt the approach
proposed in the NPRM for electing
carrier study areas exiting the NECA
traffic-sensitive tariff pool to establish
their initial BDS rates under incentive
regulation by multiplying the NECA
pool rate in effect on January 1, 2019 by
a net contribution or net recipient factor
or by doing so using the NECA pool rate
in effect on January 1, 2020 for carriers
electing conversion in 2020. No
commenters opposed this proposal.
Electing carriers exiting the NECA pool
will adjust the NECA pool rate to reflect
the extent they are either a net
contributor or net recipient in order to
ensure their rates are just and
reasonable. Each NECA pool member
receives a settlement from the pool
based on its costs plus a pro rata share
of the earnings, or based on its
settlement pursuant to the average
schedule formulas. NECA pool rates are
lower than necessary for a net recipient
to recover its revenue requirement, or
higher than necessary for a net
contributor to recover its revenue
requirement and must be adjusted by
the extent to which the existing study
area is a net contributor to, or net
recipient from, the NECA pool in order
to satisfy the just and reasonable
PO 00000
Frm 00070
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
standard. Without an adjustment,
electing carriers’ BDS rates would be
either artificially high or low going
forward.
33. First, to determine the appropriate
net contributor or net recipient factor,
electing carriers exiting the pool
effective July 1, 2019 will determine
their interstate special access revenue
for the period July 1 to December 31,
2018. An electing carrier exiting the
NECA tariff shall determine its pool
settlements to be used in developing the
factor based on costs for the period July
1 through December 31, 2018, which
reflects the first six months of tariff year
2018–19, the 12-month period for which
the costs underlying the January 1, 2019
rates were projected. The pool
settlements shall be adjusted to reflect
the 10.5% rate of return which was used
to establish the revenue requirement for
the January 1, 2019 rates. Second,
carriers will calculate the difference
between the exiting pool member’s
interstate special access revenues for
July 1 to December 31, 2018 and special
access pool settlements reflecting the
authorized rate of return for this same
period. Third, this net contribution or
net recipient amount will then be
divided by interstate special access
revenues for the same period to produce
a percent net contribution or net
recipient factor. Fourth, carriers shall
proportionately adjust their special
access NECA pool rates in effect on
January 1, 2019 downward by the net
contribution factor or upward by the net
recipient factor. Finally, carriers will
adjust these rates further consistent with
§§ 61.45 through 61.47 of our rules, in
the manner described above for carriers
that file their own tariffs, to set their
initial BDS rates for the first year of
incentive regulation. Carriers electing to
exit the NECA pool effective July 1,
2020 will use the same methodology to
adjust their rates but using the
corresponding dates that are one year
later.
34. We agree with Petitioners that
recommend that initial rates be based on
the existing tariffed rates at the time of
a carrier’s election of incentive
regulation. AT&T and Sprint disagree
and argue that the Commission should
adjust initial BDS rates to account for
the rate-of-return transition that is
currently underway. The Commission
adopted a six-year transition in 2016 to
reduce the then-11.25% rate of return by
25 basis points per year until the rate of
return reaches 9.75% in 2021. AT&T
and Sprint argue that the Commission
should adjust electing carriers’ initial
BDS rates to reflect the fullytransitioned 9.75% rate of return or, at
a minimum, Sprint argues that the
E:\FR\FM\28DER1.SGM
28DER1
amozie on DSK3GDR082PROD with RULES
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 248 / Friday, December 28, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
Commission should adjust the price
capped rates each year during the rateof-return transition until it ends in 2021.
AT&T claims that ‘‘[s]etting electing A–
CAM carriers’ initial rate-of-return at the
9.75% level immediately upon
converting to price cap, while not
completely correcting, would help
alleviate any rate disparities and aligns
with the Commission’s finding that a
9.75% rate of return is more than
reasonable.’’
35. We find that existing tariffed rates
targeting the transitional 10.5% rate of
return in effect is the more appropriate
rate from which to launch incentive
regulation for carriers electing to
convert to incentive regulation effective
July 1, 2019. AT&T and Sprint fail to
accord any significance to the
Commission’s decision to implement
changes in the prescribed rate of return
over six years and the reasons for such
a measured and lengthy transition. In
granting a six-year transition, the
Commission acknowledged that ‘‘for
almost 25 years, rate-of-return carriers
have made significant infrastructure
investments . . . and that represcribing
the rate of return will have a financial
impact on these carriers.’’ Rate-of-return
carriers’ business plans and long-term
capital investments are typically based
on an expected multi-year revenue
stream. The Commission determined
that an immediate transition to a 9.75%
rate of return would disrupt these
carriers’ reasonable reliance on these
expected revenues. The Commission
also recognized that ‘‘rate-of-return
incumbent LECs have been subject to
significant regulatory changes in recent
years, and that such changes are
occurring at a time when these carriers
are attempting to transition their
networks and service offerings to a
broadband world.’’ Reflecting the
balance of the six-year transition
whether through a one-time adjustment,
or through a series of three adjustments,
would abandon this careful transition
and would likely disrupt electing
carriers’ ability to invest in upgrading
and transitioning their networks to
provide broadband in the rural
communities they serve.
36. We also find that once a carrier
elects incentive regulation, its rates
should be based on that form of
regulation and not effectively a hybrid
or combination of rate-of-return and
incentive regulation, which would be
the result were we to adopt the annual
adjustment the Commission has applied
to carriers that are subject to cost-based
rate-of-return regulation as proposed by
Sprint. Capping BDS rates of an electing
carrier that will be subject to incentive
regulation and reducing them annually
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:02 Dec 27, 2018
Jkt 247001
by the X-factor going forward will be
sufficient to ensure these rates are just
and reasonable while at the same time
creating the right incentives to operate
efficiently—a goal we cannot expect to
achieve by continuing to overlay rate-ofreturn obligations on top of an incentive
regulation scheme. An annual 25 basis
point adjustment would also be more
administratively burdensome to
implement. Rather than perpetuating
policies associated with an inefficient
rate-of-return system, we look to the
ongoing operation of incentive
regulation to spur carriers to be more
efficient and productive than they were
under rate-of-return regulation using Xfactor-based rate reductions.
37. Finally, as some commenters
explain, reducing initial BDS rate levels
to account for the rate-of-return
transition would ‘‘reduce the motivation
of a carrier to opt into incentive
regulation’’ contrary to the goals of this
Order and the Commission’s preference
for incentive-based regulation. If initial
BDS rates were adjusted to the fullytransitioned rate of return of 9.75%,
carriers would be able to earn a higher
return and revenue during the rate-ofreturn regulation transition that ends in
2021 than by moving to incentive
regulation. This outcome is contrary to
the Commission’s long-standing policy
preferring incentive-based regulation
over rate-of-return regulation and
encouraging conversions to incentivebased regulation. Incentive regulation
will encourage electing carriers to be
more efficient than they were under
rate-of-return regulation, and pass some
of these efficiencies on to consumers
through rate reductions (or rates that are
lower than otherwise) through the
application of a price cap formula that
reflects a properly calculated X-factor.
Accordingly, we seek to encourage
carriers to adopt incentive regulation by
allowing electing carriers to set their
initial rates under incentive regulation
based on rates reflecting the transitional
rate of return currently in effect.
38. We agree with Petitioners that
initial rates for lower capacity TDM
transport and end user channel
termination services should be based on
existing tariffed deemed lawful rates—
rates that target the effective transitional
rate of return. We therefore set initial
rates for carriers electing to convert to
incentive regulation as of July 1, 2019
for lower capacity TDM transport and
end user channel termination services
based on electing carriers’ tariffed rates
in effect on January 1, 2019, six months
prior to when incentive regulation goes
into effect on July 1, 2019. Similarly,
initial rates for carriers electing to
convert to incentive regulation as of July
PO 00000
Frm 00071
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
67103
1, 2020 will be based on the tariffed
rates in effect on January 1, 2020.
Existing tariffed rates filed pursuant to
section 204(a)(3) of the Act that take
effect, without prior suspension and
investigation, are deemed lawful and
conclusively presumed to be just and
reasonable. Setting initial rates based on
existing tariffed rates, as noted by
commenters, is ‘‘consistent with the
methodologies used in the past when
rate-of-return carriers have converted to
price cap regulation.’’ Further, the
selection of tariffed rates in effect on a
date that precedes the effective date of
incentive regulation helps prevent rapid
aggregate price increases in the period
leading up to the incentive regulation
that would inflate price cap baseline
rates. Accordingly, price cap indexes
under incentive regulation will be
initially set at a value of 100 based on
rates in effect on January 1, 2019 for
carriers electing incentive regulation as
of July 1, 2019, and on rates in effect on
January 1, 2020 for carriers electing
incentive regulation as of July 1, 2020.
Business data services rates for carriers
accepting future offers of A–CAM
support or otherwise transition away
from legacy support mechanisms will be
effective on July 1 in the year following
their election.
2. Category Relationships Unfreeze
39. We give electing carriers subject to
the category relationships freeze of our
separations rules, including any such
carriers that accept future offers of A–
CAM support or otherwise transition
away from legacy support mechanisms,
the opportunity to opt out of that freeze.
We agree with Petitioners and WTA that
the category relationships freeze creates
a cost recovery hardship for certain
carriers and a distortion in rates that
should not be incorporated into rates
that electing carriers set for lower
capacity circuit-based business data
services under incentive regulation.
40. Background. Rate-of-return
incumbent LECs use their networks and
other resources to provide both
interstate and intrastate services. The
Commission’s part 36 jurisdictional
separations rules are designed to help
prevent the recovery of the same costs
from both the interstate and intrastate
jurisdictions and require that rate-ofreturn incumbent LECs divide their
costs and revenues between the
respective jurisdictions. The
jurisdictional separations analysis
begins with categorizing the incumbent
LEC’s regulated costs and revenues, a
process requiring that the incumbent
LEC assign the regulated investments,
expenses, and revenues recorded in its
part 32 accounts to various part 36
E:\FR\FM\28DER1.SGM
28DER1
amozie on DSK3GDR082PROD with RULES
67104
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 248 / Friday, December 28, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
categories. The incumbent LEC then
directly assigns to the interstate or
intrastate jurisdiction, or allocates
between those jurisdictions, the costs or
revenues in each part 36 category.
41. In 1997, the Commission initiated
a proceeding to comprehensively reform
its jurisdictional separations rules and
referred that matter to the Federal-State
Joint Board on Jurisdictional
Separations (Joint Board) for preparation
of a recommended decision. In the 2001
Separations Freeze Order, 66 FR 33202,
June 21, 2001, the Commission froze the
jurisdictional separations rules to allow
time for the Joint Board to develop
recommendations on comprehensive
separations reform. Also, in that Order,
the Commission granted rate-of-return
carriers a one-time option to freeze their
category relationships, enabling each
carrier to determine whether such a
freeze would be beneficial ‘‘based on its
own circumstances and investment
plans.’’ Carriers that elected this freeze
assign regulated costs to separations
categories based on separations category
relationships from 2001, rather than on
current data. Presently, approximately
28 rate-of-return carriers that receive
fixed high-cost universal service
support operate under this category
relationships freeze.
42. The Commission has repeatedly
extended the separations freeze. The
most recent extension is set to expire on
December 31, 2018. In the 2018
Separations Freeze Extension
proceeding, the Commission proposed
to extend the separations freeze for 15
years, while providing a one-time
opportunity for carriers that had elected
to freeze their category relationships to
opt out of that freeze and categorize
their costs based on current data rather
than separations category results from
2001. The Commission has not yet acted
on that proposal.
43. Category Relationships Unfreeze.
The category relationships freeze has
now been in place for more than 17
years, and our rules prohibit carriers
that elected that freeze from
withdrawing from it. Rate-of-return
carriers that chose to freeze their
category relationships in 2001 assign
costs within part 32 accounts to
categories using their separations
category relationships from 2000. This
means that these companies are still
separating their costs based on the
technologies and services that were in
place in 2000, instead of being able to
adjust the amounts assigned to
separations categories to reflect the
current network costs and services that
would allow these carriers to properly
recover their costs. Investment by
carriers is becoming more weighted
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:02 Dec 27, 2018
Jkt 247001
toward BDS and away from switched
access and common line categories.
Thus, we agree with Petitioners that the
result is that some, if not all, carriers
with frozen category relationships are
unable to recover their BDS costs from
BDS customers or from NECA traffic
sensitive pool settlements.
44. We therefore allow electing
carriers to unfreeze and update their
category relationships in conjunction
with setting their initial rates, which
will enable such carriers to more closely
align their BDS rates with their
underlying costs as they set initial
incentive regulation rates. Once an
electing carrier implements incentive
regulation rates for its BDS, it will no
longer need to comply with the
separations rules by virtue of our action
below forbearing from application of the
separations and other cost assignment
rules to electing carriers. This, in turn,
will allow the carriers and their
customers to benefit from the
efficiencies of incentive regulation.
45. The Commission originally
allowed rate-of-return carriers the
flexibility to choose whether to freeze
their category relationships because
those carriers’ size, cost structures, and
investment patterns vary widely. For
similar reasons, we conclude that the
burden on electing carriers, were we to
require all impacted carriers to unfreeze
and update their category relationships,
would outweigh any benefits, and thus
grant these carriers the flexibility to
choose. For example, some carriers may
have based their current business plans
and investment on a continuation of the
freeze since it has been in effect for such
a long period and compelling these
carriers to unfreeze their categories now
could be disruptive. Further, it would
impose a disproportionate burden on
companies with cost structures that
have not changed significantly enough
to warrant the administrative costs that
these carriers would incur in updating
their relationships. Moreover, the
process of unfreezing and updating
category relationships is resourceintensive, requiring carriers to develop
detailed analyses for new categorization
cost studies. As a result, we recognize
that some electing carriers may choose
not to unfreeze their category
relationships in conjunction with
setting initial incentive regulation rates
for lower capacity circuit-based
business data services because of the
administrative costs they would incur in
updating these relationships. We see no
need to require that electing carriers
incur these costs, particularly since one
of the principal goals of this proceeding
is to reduce unnecessary regulatory
burdens.
PO 00000
Frm 00072
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
46. In adopting this option, we reject
NARUC’s contention that we are
violating section 410(c) of the
Communications Act by failing to
meaningfully consult with, and receive
a recommendation from the Joint Board.
Section 410(c) applies only to the extent
the Commission engages in ‘‘the
jurisdictional separation of common
carrier property and expenses between
interstate and intrastate operations.’’
Here, we are not engaged in that
process. Instead, we are determining
which costs electing carriers should use
to calculate their incentive regulation
rates for lower capacity circuit-based
BDS. In allowing electing carriers to set
those rates using data from 2018, rather
than 2000, we make no change to the
jurisdictional separations rules.
47. As set forth more fully below, we
direct each electing carrier that chooses
to update its separations category
relationships to conduct two cost
studies for 2018 and to use those cost
studies in determining its initial
incentive regulation rates. In so doing,
we are exercising our authority over
interstate rates and are not in any way
requiring state commissions to make
similar intrastate adjustments. On the
contrary, our forbearance from
application of the separations rules to
electing carriers will allow the states to
adopt their own rules for determining
the costs carriers incur in providing
intrastate services to the extent they
have authority under state law.
48. Moreover, even if we were to
interpret 410(c) so broadly as to be
applicable to the opportunity we
provide electing carriers to unfreeze
their category relationships, our actions
are not in conflict with our obligations
under section 410(c). In 2009, the
Commission asked the Joint Board to
consider whether the Commission
should allow carriers a one-time
opportunity to unfreeze their
separations category relationships and
requested that the Joint Board prepare a
recommended decision on that matter.
No recommendation has been
forthcoming. Section 410(c) directs that,
after a referral, the Joint Board ‘‘shall
prepare a recommended decision for
prompt review and action by the
Commission.’’ Nothing in section 410(c)
obligates the Commission to wait
indefinitely for a recommended
decision before acting. We conclude that
the only reasonable interpretation of
this statutory language allows the
Commission to act unilaterally where,
as here, an issue has been pending
before the Joint Board for more than
nine years without a recommended
decision. Any contrary interpretation
would allow the Joint Board to
E:\FR\FM\28DER1.SGM
28DER1
amozie on DSK3GDR082PROD with RULES
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 248 / Friday, December 28, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
indefinitely delay Commission action.
Congress could not have intended that
result while requiring that that the
Commission act promptly once the Joint
Board issues a recommended decision.
49. Section 410(c) also requires that
the Commission ‘‘afford the State
members of the Joint Board an
opportunity to participate in its
deliberations’’ on ‘‘decisional action[s]’’
regarding matters that have been
referred to the Joint Board. To the extent
this provision can be read as applying
to this proceeding, the notice and
comment periods and permit-butdisclose rules governing this proceeding
have provided plenty of opportunity for
the state members of the Joint Board to
voice their opinions on allowing
electing carriers to opt out of the
category relationships freeze.
50. Implementation. To ensure that
updated category relationships are
properly reflected in incentive
regulation rates, we require each
electing carrier that chooses to update
its frozen category relationships to
conduct two 2018 cost studies—one
based on frozen category relationships
and one based on unfrozen
relationships. To determine its incentive
regulation rates for BDS, the carrier
shall divide the BDS costs under the
revised 2018 cost study by the BDS
costs determined in the original 2018
cost study using frozen category
relationships to develop a rate
adjustment factor. The carrier shall
apply this factor to the initial (prior to
adjustments for the X-factor, inflation
factor, and any exogenous cost changes)
rates established in accordance with the
procedures explained elsewhere in this
Order to set the carrier’s initial rates for
lower capacity circuit-based BDS under
incentive regulation. The carrier shall
adjust these rates for the X-factor,
inflation factor, and any exogenous cost
changes and may adjust these rates to
reflect any pricing flexibility allowed
among services within the special
access basket. Carriers that elect
incentive regulation effective as of July
1, 2020 will follow these directions,
except that if an electing carrier chooses
to update its frozen category
relationships it will conduct two 2019
cost studies and use the results of these
cost studies to complete the steps
described in this paragraph.
51. Unfreezing separations category
relationships could result in a carrier
recovering the same costs through
higher BDS rates and unchanged
switched access recovery. Incorporating
updated category relationships into the
2018 cost study, or 2019 cost study for
carriers electing the January 1, 2020
effective date, will change the costs
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:02 Dec 27, 2018
Jkt 247001
assigned to the switched access category
just as it will for BDS. The USF/ICC
Transformation Order capped all
interstate switched access rates at 2011
levels, subject to specified reductions
over time. We do not permit electing
carriers to increase their switched
access rate caps. Unless cost reductions
to interstate switched access are
reflected in a carrier’s revised base
period revenue amount, a carrier will
double-recover costs through its
interstate switched access rates. To
account for this effect, an electing
carrier that unfreezes its separations
category relationships must calculate
the difference between the interstate
switched access costs in the two 2018
cost studies. Each electing carrier must
adjust its base period revenue by an
amount equal to the interstate switched
access cost difference between the two
2018 cost studies before applying the
annual 5% reduction to the base period
revenue. This is the process that the
Commission employed in the Eastex
proceeding. Carriers electing a January
1, 2020 effective date will do the same
with 2019 cost studies.
52. An electing carrier that
participates in the NECA interstate
switched access tariff must report to
NECA the interstate switched access
cost difference between the two 2018,
or, 2019, studies and its revised base
period revenue amount. These
procedures protect both carriers and
customers from any unintended
consequences of moving BDS from rateof-return regulation to incentive
regulation. Any electing carrier that opts
out of the category relationships freeze
shall include, in its 2019 or 2020,
respectively, annual filing, workpapers
showing how it implemented the
measures set forth above. This does not
eliminate the need for an electing carrier
to adjust its Eligible Recovery for any
other instances of double recovery.
Finally, we require NECA to reflect
these base period revenue changes in its
settlement procedures.
53. We find that these measures
provide a reasonable and not unduly
burdensome method for ensuring that
costs shifted from an electing carrier’s
unfreezing of its category relationships
are carried forward into its incentive
regulation rates for BDS without any
double-recovery. Each electing carrier
that chooses to update its category
relationships will necessarily need to
perform detailed calculations to
implement that choice. We minimize
the associated burdens by specifying
that the electing carrier adjust its
business data service rates to account
for the changes in the category
relationships using the 2018 cost study,
PO 00000
Frm 00073
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
67105
or the 2019 cost study for carriers
electing to convert effective July 1, 2020,
that this Order requires of all electing
carriers and therefore will impose only
a minimal incremental burden on
electing carriers.
3. Special Access Basket, Categories,
and Subcategories
54. We retain the special access
basket, categories and subcategories,
and the attendant rules governing the
allowed annual rate adjustments for
price cap regulation for incentive
regulation. Commenting parties support
this approach. The category and subcategory requirements limit the degree
to which a carrier can raise rates for
particular groups of services in any
given year. Each electing carrier that
elects incentive regulation must set its
initial price cap indexes for the special
access basket and associated service
band indices at 100 and use the rate
adjustment rules for price cap carriers
contained in §§ 61.45 to 61.48 of our
rules, as appropriate, to reflect the
prescribed productivity factor, the
inflation factor, and any required
exogenous cost adjustment in the price
cap index. These steps will ensure that
the carrier’s actual price index does not
exceed its price cap index, and that its
service band indexes for each category
or subcategory do not exceed their
upper limits.
4. Productivity X-Factor and Measure of
Inflation
55. Consistent with the price cap BDS
Order, we adopt 2.0% as the
productivity factor (X-factor) and the
Gross Domestic Product-Price Index
(GDP–PI) as the inflation factor used to
adjust price cap indexes in the first year
of incentive regulation, and each year
thereafter. As proposed in the NPRM,
we decline to incorporate a consumer
productivity dividend adjustment into
the X-factor.
56. Background. Under price cap
regulation, the price cap index seeks to
replicate the beneficial cost-reducing
incentives of a competitive market by
limiting the prices that a price cap LEC
may charge for services. After price cap
carriers set initial price cap indexes
based on going-in rate levels, these
indexes are adjusted annually based
primarily on the productivity factor (Xfactor) and inflation factor (GDP–PI) as
well as any exogenous cost adjustments.
The X-factor adjustment is intended to
capture the amount by which
incumbent LECs could be expected to
outperform economy-wide productivity
gains and to pass those gains on to
consumers in the form of lower prices.
In the past, the Commission has also
E:\FR\FM\28DER1.SGM
28DER1
amozie on DSK3GDR082PROD with RULES
67106
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 248 / Friday, December 28, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
applied a consumer productivity
dividend adjustment to the X-factor to
capture for ratepayers a portion of the
benefits from expected productivity
gains exceeding those incumbent LECs
had historically achieved under rate-ofreturn regulation. The inflation factor is
intended to adjust prices to capture
economy-wide rates of inflation.
Historically, the Commission has used
the U.S. Department of Commerce’s
Bureau of Economic Analysis’s GDP–PI,
a chain-weighted index of overall
national prices, as the inflation factor.
57. In the BDS Order, the Commission
adopted for price cap carriers a 2.0%
productivity-based X-factor and retained
GDP–PI as the inflation factor but
declined to apply a consumer
productivity dividend adjustment. The
Commission found that 2.0% reflects its
best estimate of the productivity growth
that incumbent LECs will experience in
the provision of BDS services relative to
productivity growth in the overall
economy. To determine the X-factor, the
Commission applied a total factor
productivity methodology, which
measures the relationship between the
output of goods and services to inputs.
The Commission applied this
methodology to the U.S. Bureau of
Labor Statistics’ Capital, Labor, Energy,
Materials, and Services (KLEMS) dataset
for the broadcasting and
telecommunications industries for
estimating incumbent LEC productivity
and input prices. The Commission used
these data to establish a zone of
reasonable X-factor estimates based on
four relevant time periods, and from this
zone selected an X-factor of 2.0%. The
Commission also retained GDP–PI as the
measure of inflation. Accordingly, price
cap LECs adjust their price cap indexes
annually by the 2.0% X-factor and GDP–
PI to ensure just and reasonable rates for
these BDS services.
58. Discussion. Consistent with the
BDS Order, we adopt 2.0% as the
productivity factor electing carriers will
use to adjust their price cap indexes. In
so doing, we reaffirm the Commission’s
finding in the BDS Order that the 2.0%
X-factor represents our best estimate of
BDS productivity gains or losses relative
to the general economy and is a
reasonable productivity factor with
which to adjust price cap indexes for
purposes of incentive regulation.
59. WTA opposes adoption of the
2.0% productivity X-factor for incentive
regulation, contending that ‘‘given
increasing broadband-related labor costs
and the fact that the typical WTA
member has only 10-to-20 employees, it
does not appear possible for many small
A–CAM and Alaska Plan companies to
achieve productivity gains of two
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:02 Dec 27, 2018
Jkt 247001
percent each year.’’ We believe,
however, that the 2.0% X-factor is the
most reliable estimate of BDS
productivity growth for carriers
generally, including smaller carriers.
The 2.0% X-factor was the product of an
economically-sound total factor
productivity methodology, consistent
with past Commission practice, using
the only reliable and internally
consistent dataset in the record in the
BDS proceeding, KLEMS, for measuring
incumbent LEC productivity and input
prices. WTA focuses on one type of
input price—labor costs—for which
KLEMS captures telecommunications
industry trends, including broadbandrelated trends, for carriers of all sizes.
WTA implicitly assumes that its
members’ labor costs will rise more
quickly (or fall more slowly) than price
cap carriers’ labor costs. Even if we were
to accept this assumption, WTA does
not address whether other factors
affecting BDS productivity growth, such
as changes in BDS demand, offset any
disparity in the rate of change in labor
costs.
60. The Commission sought comment
on alternative X-factors for electing
carriers but received no data or other
information that would allow us to
calculate an alternative X-factor. And
while WTA provides anecdotal data on
a selected portion of its members’ costs,
it has ‘‘not submitted the companyspecific input price and output data that
we would need to quantify’’ the extent
to which its members’ productivity
growth and ability to recover costs
deviate from the industry average. In the
BDS Order, the Commission declined to
adjust the X-factor to account for
conflicting and unquantifiable evidence
in the record that the KLEMS dataset
overstated or understated productivity
growth. And the Eighth Circuit Court of
Appeals upheld the Commission’s
decision not to adjust the KLEMS
dataset ‘‘in light of the conflicting
evidence on what sort of adjustment
was appropriate.’’ In these
circumstances, we see no valid basis on
which to adopt an alternative X-factor.
61. Notwithstanding WTA’s concerns,
we believe that most electing carriers
will be able to achieve the 2.0% Xfactor. Petitioners support our use of a
2.0% X-factor, even though they state
that rate-of-return carriers may generally
achieve lower productivity growth than
price cap carriers, and TDS Telecom
endorses the regulatory framework
adopted in the BDS Order that includes
a 2.0% X-factor. Given that rate-ofreturn carriers receiving fixed support
are not required to move to incentive
regulation, carriers unable to achieve
the 2.0% X-factor will avoid any harm
PO 00000
Frm 00074
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
by simply not electing incentive
regulation. The voluntary nature of
incentive regulation therefore renders
moot any risk involved in attempting
today to determine what an appropriate
productivity factor would be for this
group of carriers. Carriers themselves
are in the best position to determine
whether they will benefit from incentive
regulation and we have afforded them
that flexibility.
62. Inflation Factor. We adopt GDP–
PI as the inflation factor as proposed in
the NPRM. No commenter opposed this
proposal. As we found in the BDS
Order, there is no alternative measure of
inflation presented in the record that is
as accurate as GDP–PI in the mediumand long-term and that is not
susceptible to carrier influence or
manipulation. Accordingly, electing
carriers will adjust their price cap
indexes by GDP–PI during the first year
of incentive regulation, and each year
thereafter.
63. Consumer Productivity Dividend.
We decline to incorporate a consumer
productivity dividend adjustment into
the X-factor adopted in this Order. No
commenter opposed this proposal in the
NPRM. In the BDS Order, the
Commission found that the 2.0% Xfactor reflected all anticipated future
BDS productivity growth and declined
to include a consumer productivity
dividend adjustment in the X-factor. For
similar reasons, and to avoid regulatory
disparity with price cap regulation, we
decline to include a consumer
productivity dividend in the X-factor for
incentive regulation.
5. Exogenous Costs
64. After reviewing the record, we
adopt the proposal in the NPRM that
exogenous costs be allocated based on a
ratio of BDS revenues to total revenues
from all regulated services and an
electing carrier’s universal service
support payments. Exogenous costs are
those costs that are beyond the control
of the carrier, as determined by the
Commission. We agree with Petitioners
that allowing exogenous cost
adjustments is appropriate. When costs
are beyond the carrier’s control, they are
often of a nature that is not reflected in
the measurement of productivity. It is
therefore appropriate to allow
adjustments to reflect exogenous events
upon Commission approval.
65. We reject Sprint’s proposal that
any exogenous cost changes should be
limited by applying the ratio of BDS
revenues to total enterprise revenues.
Sprint does not define ‘‘total enterprise
revenues’’ or explain why it would
result in a more relevant comparison to
BDS revenues than using total regulated
E:\FR\FM\28DER1.SGM
28DER1
amozie on DSK3GDR082PROD with RULES
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 248 / Friday, December 28, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
revenues, and we find it too expansive
for use here. The exogenous costs being
allocated are those associated with
regulated services as determined by the
part 64 allocation rules for assigning
costs associated with non-regulated
activities. Thus, we find that regulated
BDS revenues compared to all regulated
revenues and related support receipts is
the most relevant relationship to
allocate a portion of exogenous costs
related to regulated services to BDS.
66. Finally, we will not require
electing carriers to incur the costs of
filing a short form tariff review plan as
price cap carriers are required to do. In
recent years, the Bureau has waived the
requirement that price cap LECs file the
short form, finding that it would
provide little value to the Commission,
industry, and consumers. We find that
the short form tariff review plan would
also provide little value to the
Commission, industry, and consumers
in conjunction with incentive regulation
for electing carriers. We accordingly do
not require its filing.
return carriers as the benchmark for
establishing the low-end adjustment as
we did in the BDS Order. This approach
will approximate the transition to the
authorized rate of return of 9.75%. A
carrier asserting a claim for a low-end
adjustment bears the burden of showing
that its return is below the prescribed
benchmark and that the revised rate(s)
are consistent with the benchmark.
70. Finally, as the Commission
proposed in the NPRM, electing carriers
that exercise downward pricing
flexibility (for example, by entering into
a contract tariff with a customer), or use
generally accepted accounting
principles (GAAP) rather than the part
32 Uniform System of Accounts, will be
ineligible for a low-end adjustment. No
party has opposed this limitation to the
availability of the low-end adjustment
mechanism. This limitation is
consistent with that imposed in the BDS
Order, and we see no reason to diverge
from that approach here.
6. Low-end Adjustment
67. We adopt the low-end adjustment
mechanism proposed in the NPRM to
provide an appropriate backstop to
ensure that electing carriers are not
subject to protracted periods of low
earnings. A below-normal rate of return
over a prolonged period could threaten
a carrier’s ability to raise the capital
necessary to provide modern, efficient
services to customers. The low-end
adjustment mechanism will permit a
one-time adjustment to a single year’s
BDS rates to avoid back-to-back annual
earnings below a set benchmark. This
course should allow electing carriers to
meet their existing obligations to
debtholders and attract sufficient capital
while continuing to provide BDS.
68. We reject Sprint’s argument that
any low-end adjustment should be
allowed only if a sharing mechanism is
adopted for a carrier’s earnings. A
sharing mechanism is a process that
allocates a portion of a carrier’s excess
earnings under price cap regulation to
the consumer through a one-time
reduction in a carrier’s price cap index.
The Commission eliminated the sharing
mechanism for price cap carriers in
1997. There is no causal link between
the low-end adjustment mechanism and
earnings sharing, and the two have not
previously been tied together in other
incentive regulation programs. The BDS
Order allowed a low-end adjustment
without a sharing mechanism and
Sprint provides no convincing basis for
diverging from that approach.
69. We use 100 basis points below the
authorized rate of return for rate-of-
7. Pricing Flexibility for Lower Capacity
TDM Transport and End User Channel
Termination Services
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:02 Dec 27, 2018
Jkt 247001
71. We adopt the proposal in the
NPRM to grant pricing flexibility to
electing carriers for their lower capacity
TDM transport and end user channel
termination services under incentive
regulation similar to the pricing
flexibility the Commission granted to
price cap carriers’ lower capacity TDM
end user channel terminations in areas
deemed non-competitive. We agree with
commenters that permitting electing
carriers to offer contract tariff pricing
and volume and term discounts will
benefit both carriers and customers and
will promote competition in electing
carriers’ BDS markets. Requiring that
electing carriers also maintain generally
available tariff rates for their lower
capacity TDM transport and end user
channel termination services will
ensure that the rates of customers that
do not negotiate contract-based or term
and volume discounted rates for such
services will continue to be just and
reasonable. Additionally, we condition
this grant of pricing flexibility on the
requirement that electing carriers
remove contract tariff demand from the
relevant incentive regulation basket for
purposes of determining their price cap
indexes and actual price indexes, which
will ensure that those customers that do
not negotiate contract tariffs will not
cross-subsidize customers that do.
PO 00000
Frm 00075
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
67107
C. Removal of Ex Ante Pricing
Regulation of Lower Capacity TDM End
User Channel Termination Services in
Areas Deemed Competitive
72. As part of our framework for
moving electing carriers to less intrusive
pricing regulation of their BDS offerings,
we adopt a competitive market test to
identify those areas served by electing
carriers where competition or potential
competition for lower speed (DS3 or
less) TDM end user channel termination
services justifies removing ex ante
pricing regulation for those services. In
adopting a competitive market test for
electing carriers, we are guided by the
Commission’s previous work in
developing a competitive market test for
price cap carriers’ BDS offerings. At the
same time, we are persuaded by
commenters that argue that the
competitive market test should rely on
evidence of competition in the study
areas served by electing carriers.
73. We adopt a competitive market
test for electing carriers that is based on
a modified version of the second prong
of the BDS Order competitive market
test, which uses publicly available Form
477 data to measure whether a cable
operator offers a minimum of 10/1 Mbps
in 75% of census blocks in a study area
served by a price cap provider. We will
apply this test in electing carriers’ study
areas, and in those study areas deemed
competitive by the competitive market
test, we remove ex ante pricing
regulation of lower capacity TDM end
user channel terminations.
74. We are also constrained in the
development of a competitive market
test by the limited availability of data in
the record regarding competition for
BDS services in the study areas served
by eligible rate-of-return carriers. We
decline, however, to adopt any of the
options we proposed in the NPRM for a
competitive market test that would
require a new data collection.
Commenters strongly oppose a new
information collection, arguing it would
be burdensome and unnecessary. We
agree. A new information collection for
electing carriers would be especially
burdensome given their relatively
smaller size. The Commission similarly
declined to require a new data
collection even for larger price cap
carriers in the BDS Order, as part of
deciding to update the price cap
competitive market test results, finding
that the burdens would outweigh the
benefits, and the burden of collecting
the information would be considerable.
Additionally, the burdens associated
with an information collection could
reduce incentives for eligible carriers to
elect incentive regulation, counter to
E:\FR\FM\28DER1.SGM
28DER1
67108
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 248 / Friday, December 28, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
our goals. A simple, administrable test
will ensure more resources are available
for competition and deployment in
electing carriers’ study areas.
75. In the NPRM, we sought comment
on whether to include lower capacity
TDM transport services in the
competitive market test. Given the lack
of data in our record, we find that
including such transport services would
be unworkable at this time. We therefore
decline to adopt a competitive market
test for lower capacity TDM transport in
electing carriers’ study areas.
amozie on DSK3GDR082PROD with RULES
1. Criteria for a Competitive Market Test
76. In this section, we address
appropriate criteria for a competitive
market test for electing carriers’ lower
speed TDM end user channel
termination services, including the
appropriate product market, number of
competitors in a market, and geographic
market.
77. Product market. When defining a
product market, to ensure our action
affects an appropriate group of services,
we look to which services are
sufficiently similar to reasonably be
considered substitutes. We find the
Commission’s analysis of the relevant
market in the BDS Order to be
applicable to the current situation, and,
therefore find the relevant product
market includes circuit- and packetbased business data services, legacy
hybrid-fiber-coaxial, and copper. For the
same reason, we find that the product
market also includes unbundled
network elements, dark fiber, and fixed
wireless services and facilities used to
provision BDS. These services play
competitive roles in BDS markets. While
the Commission did not find best-efforts
services to be close substitutes for all
types of BDS in the BDS Order, we
acknowledge here as the Commission
did there that they nonetheless place a
degree of competitive pressure on BDS
suppliers, particularly for lower
capacity services. Further, we believe a
best-efforts supplier with its own
ubiquitous wireline network has strong
incentives to supply BDS to locations
where it currently does not, and all the
more so to the extent that an existing
supplier is charging supra-competitive
prices. We also continue to expect that
suppliers exercising any short-term
market power generally will be
constrained by supply-side substitution
over the medium term (3–5 years) in
locations where other providers, such as
cable companies, offer best-efforts or
other telecommunications services over
their own facilities. We therefore find
that the product market analysis that the
Commission conducted for price cap
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:02 Dec 27, 2018
Jkt 247001
areas in the BDS Order applies equally
to electing carrier areas.
78. Competition Within a Study Area.
We must also determine the appropriate
level of competition for any competitive
market test. The Commission, in the
BDS Order determined that a
‘‘combination of either one competitive
provider with a network within a half
mile from a location served by an
incumbent LEC or a cable operator’s
facilities in the same census block as a
location with demand will provide
competitive restraint’’ more effectively
than legacy regulation. The Commission
decided that a ‘‘nearby’’ BDS competitor
provides sufficient competition after
analyzing three findings: (1) The
geographic scope within which a likely
BDS provider can realistically compete
with an incumbent LEC; (2) a finding
that one competitor in addition to the
incumbent LEC provides a reasonable
degree of competition; and, (3) the
benefits of competition outweigh the
potential unintended costs of regulation.
79. We do not have data showing
where there is a competitive provider
with a network half a mile from a
location served by carriers eligible to
elect the lighter touch regulatory
framework we adopt today. We do,
however, have Form 477 data which is
organized on a census block-level. We
can therefore identify the census blocks
served by an electing carrier where
cable broadband services are also
deployed. We find it appropriate to use
cable broadband in the census blocks
that comprise the electing carrier’s
study area as a proxy for competition
because, as the Commission previously
determined, ‘‘cable companies have
focused investment on building fiber
networks for higher-bandwidth Ethernet
services, which is enabling them to
overcome limitations of traditional
coaxial-based cable systems that cannot
meet higher bandwidth demand.’’ Cable
providers have shifted to offering
‘‘higher (and more competitive)
bandwidths. At the same time, cable
operators’ best efforts (and Ethernet over
Hybrid Fiber-coaxial (EoHFC)) services
continue to compete effectively against
incumbent LECs’ lower speed TDM
services. The Commission also found
that because cable operators have
‘‘aggressive[ly] deploy[ed]’’ it was
‘‘highly likely the cable-only measure
found in the Form 477 data will capture
the vast bulk of additional deployments;
it is likely that most non-cable
competitive extension of business data
services networks will occur where
cable is also deploying or has already
deployed.’’ This rationale is equally
applicable to electing carriers’ provision
of BDS in their study areas.
PO 00000
Frm 00076
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
80. As the Commission found in the
BDS Order, and as the Eighth Circuit
Court affirmed, a single wireline
competitor provides a substantial
competitive effect by disciplining rates,
terms, and conditions to just and
reasonable levels. In industries with
large sunk costs, such as wireline
providers, the largest impact occurs
with the entry of a second provider,
with added benefits from additional
competitors declining thereafter. This is
because the presence of a nearby
provider is likely to prevent or mitigate
substantial abuse of market power,
either through lack of innovation or
high prices. This finding is not
challenged in the record. Consistent
with the analysis in the BDS Order, we
find that the effect of a single BDS
competitor is sufficient to limit
anticompetitive behavior, and that the
presence of a cable network offering a
minimum of 10/1 Mbps broadband
service in 75% of the census blocks in
a study area is sufficient to deem a
study area competitive for the purposes
of the competitive market test for
electing carriers.
81. Geographic Market. We find that
an electing carrier’s individual study
area is the appropriate geographic
market measure for the competitive
market test because it is
administratively feasible but is granular
enough to capture reasonably similar
competitive conditions. A study area is
a geographic segment of a rate-of-return
incumbent LEC’s telephone operations
that generally corresponds to the
carrier’s entire service territory within a
state. Incumbent LECs determine
eligibility for high-cost universal service
support at the study area level, perform
jurisdictional separations at the study
area level and generally tariff their rates
at the study area level. As a result, the
Commission and the industry have
substantial experience administering
rules on a study area basis. What’s more,
a study area is granular enough to
capture reasonably similar competitive
conditions. Rate-of-return study areas
vary in size but are significantly smaller
than metropolitan statistical areas and
generally smaller than counties and are
therefore sufficiently granular to assess
competitive conditions. Given their
mostly rural nature, the average size of
a rate-of-return study area is 992.82
square miles, compared to the average
county, 1,180.40 square miles, and the
average metropolitan statistical area,
2,720.95 square miles. Adopting study
areas as the geographic market also
avoids risk of competitive overlap by,
for example, a rate-of-return study area
E:\FR\FM\28DER1.SGM
28DER1
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 248 / Friday, December 28, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
amozie on DSK3GDR082PROD with RULES
crossing county lines that are deemed
competitive and noncompetitive.
82. We also reject other proposals in
the record, including suggestions to
build a competitive market test for
electing carriers that uses counties or
census blocks as the relevant geographic
market. We agree with Smithville that
the selection of counties for use in the
price cap competitive market test was ‘‘a
well-documented effective approach for
competitive area evaluation for larger
price cap carriers that operate service
areas dimensioned at statewide levels
but does not work well for carriers that
have sub-county service areas.’’ To the
extent such proposals seek to assess
competition in electing carriers’ study
areas based on competition elsewhere
within the county, we reject that
proposition—any competitive market
test must be based on the competitive
conditions each carrier faces, not those
another carrier faces somewhere else in
a county. Additionally, some study
areas cross county lines. Using counties
would potentially require us to
subdivide study areas along county
boundaries, which would involve
unreasonable administrative burdens
and could lead to varying treatment of
a single study area depending on the
counties in which it is located.
83. In response to the 2017 Public
Notice, Smithville argues that using
census blocks to assess competition in
electing carriers’ study areas would be
a better approach. We decline to adopt
census blocks as a geographic measure
for our competitive market test. The
Commission previously found that
census blocks or census tracts are too
numerous to efficiently administer.
Additionally, they can be impacted by
changes in demand as small as a single
building and could lead to a patchwork
of different regulations that vary from
census block-to-census block, or even
building-to-building. Study areas, on the
other hand, are more administratively
feasible because there are a limited
number of study areas eligible to elect
our BDS regulatory framework.
2. Competitive Market Test
Methodology
84. In this section, we describe the
specific structure of the electing
carriers’ competitive market test we
adopt for electing carriers’ lower
capacity TDM end user channel
termination services. In determining
whether electing carriers with lower
capacity TDM-based end user channel
termination services (at a DS3 or below),
face sufficient competition to allow
competition, rather than ex ante pricing
regulation, to ensure rates are just and
reasonable, we adopt a competitive
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:02 Dec 27, 2018
Jkt 247001
market test modeled on a modified
version of the second prong of the
existing price cap competitive market
test using data from census blocks
served by electing carriers. The second
prong of the price cap competitive
market test uses Form 477 data to
measure whether a cable operator offers
a minimum of 10/1 Mbps broadband
service in 75% of the census blocks in
the price-cap service areas within a
county. Having decided that we will use
only existing data to gauge competition
in the study areas served by an electing
carrier, for purposes of the electing
carriers’ competitive market test, if a
cable operator or other competitive
provider offers a minimum of 10/1
Mbps broadband service in 75% of the
census blocks in an electing carrier’s
study area, we will deem the study area
competitive.
85. We set 10 Mbps downstream and
1 Mbps upstream as minimum
thresholds for a cable operator’s service
to be included in the competitive
market test. Setting a minimum
threshold ensures that the networks that
supply these services are reasonable
proxies for the type of network facilities
needed to deliver BDS. As we observed
in the BDS Order, ‘‘when a cable
provider is capable of providing internet
broadband service within any census
block, then generally they have the
incentive to make the incremental
investment necessary to serve locations
with BDS demand in that census block,
especially over the medium term.’’
Cable operators are continuing to invest
in and upgrade the capacities of their
networks, which give us reasonable
assurance that these networks will be
capable of providing BDS competition
over the short- to medium-term.
Additionally, the 10/1 Mbps threshold
is also the threshold that rate-of-return
carriers accepting fixed A–CAM support
are required to offer to funded locations.
86. Using Form 477 data for electing
carriers’ study areas is administratively
simple for both the Commission and
electing carriers. We already regularly
require providers to update their Form
477 submissions, so we do not need to
undertake a new data collection.
Another benefit of the new electing
carriers’ competitive market test is the
incorporation of the 78 rate-of-returnonly counties that cannot be analyzed
using the price cap competitive market
test. Had we decided to allow electing
carriers to opt-in to the price cap
competitive market test, the competitive
status of electing carriers serving any of
those 78 rate-of-return-only counties
would have been unresolved because
they were not included in the original
analysis.
PO 00000
Frm 00077
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
67109
87. We recognize that under the
electing carriers’ competitive market
test, a relatively small percentage of
electing carriers’ study areas will be
deemed competitive at this time. The
current result of the competitive market
test we adopt today for rate-of-return
carriers receiving fixed support is
consistent with the rural nature and the
nascent deployment of cable in many
eligible carriers’ study areas. We expect
the number of electing carriers’ study
areas deemed competitive by the
competitive market test will increase as
competition grows and cable companies
expand their reach. This
administratively simple competitive
market test ensures that all carriers are
included in the electing carriers’
competitive market test and will have
an opportunity to be deregulated as
competition develops.
3. Declining To Use the Results of the
Price Cap Competitive Market Test
88. Notwithstanding Petitioners’ and
some other commenters’ request that we
use the results of the price cap
competitive market test adopted by the
Commission in the BDS Order to
determine where ex ante pricing
regulation should be removed from
electing carriers’ lower capacity TDM
end user channel termination services,
we decline to do so. In arguing that the
Commission should use the BDS Order
price cap competitive market test for
electing rate-of-return carriers, some
commenters claim ‘‘the same
marketplace analyses the Commission
undertook for price cap carriers apply
equally to BDS provided by modelbased rate-of-return carriers.’’ While
using the results of the existing
competitive market test to determine
whether an area served by an electing
carrier is competitive would be fast, no
data in the record support that
approach. In fact, the result of the
competitive market test we adopt for
electing carriers, which results in very
few study areas being deemed
competitive, underscores our finding
that application of the price cap
competitive market test results to
electing carriers—which would result in
far more electing carriers’ study areas
being deemed competitive—would not
accurately measure competition in the
geographic areas served by rate-of-return
carriers receiving fixed support.
89. The BDS Order relied upon the
largest information collection in the
history of the Commission to analyze
and determine the competitive nature of
price cap carrier study areas. Even if a
county contained both price cap and
rate-of-return study areas, the
Commission’s analysis only included
E:\FR\FM\28DER1.SGM
28DER1
amozie on DSK3GDR082PROD with RULES
67110
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 248 / Friday, December 28, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
the price cap study area. The
Commission created the price cap
competitive market test after a thorough
review of the 2015 Collection, Form 477
data, and established the specific test
metrics based upon an informed
knowledge of the level of competition
that existed and was necessary to
protect consumers in the absence of
regulation. Petitioners, however, offer
no data showing the extent of BDS
competition in areas served by rate-ofreturn carriers that receive fixed
support. Instead, they argue that the
level of competition on a county-bycounty basis for price cap carriers’ lower
capacity TDM-based BDS offerings is
comparable to the level of competition
for lower capacity TDM-based BDS
offerings of rate-of-return carriers that
receive fixed support. The principal
support Petitioners offer for this
assertion is a study that purports to
demonstrate that price cap rural areas
immediately proximate to certain A–
CAM study areas exhibit sufficiently
similar characteristics that we should
include A–CAM study areas in the same
competitive market test that we used for
price cap carriers. We find the
Petitioners’ study unpersuasive.
90. The study suffers from several
methodological defects. First, the study
is not based on a representative sample
of electing carriers’ study areas. Instead,
it relies solely on Consolidated
Communications’ rate-of-return study
areas. We are doubtful, for example, that
the Consolidated study areas are a good
proxy for the Alaska rate-of-return
carriers that are eligible to elect our new
regulatory framework. Second, two of
the study’s principal metrics
(population and housing density) are
unlikely to be the critical drivers of
competitive BDS deployment.
91. Additionally, in some instances
the study compares non-urbanized price
cap areas with areas served by rate-ofreturn carriers that receive fixed support
that include urbanized areas. These
areas are not comparable. At least some
of the counties included in the study’s
comparison were deemed noncompetitive by the price cap
competitive market test. Inclusion in the
price cap competitive market test of A–
CAM areas in these instances would
have no effect on the regulatory status
of these study areas. The study does not
directly compare study areas with high
cable presence with competitive
counties and study areas with low cable
presence with non-competitive
counties, as would be expected if the
study was trying to show similarities.
92. The study also compares the
percentage of census blocks with cable
broadband availability between price
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:02 Dec 27, 2018
Jkt 247001
cap and nearby A–CAM areas and
claims that, on average, ‘‘the percentage
of Census blocks in Consolidated tracts
with cable service (21%) is similar to
the surrounding rural price cap tracts
(28%).’’ But the study’s use of average
percentages obscures wide variations in
percentage cable broadband
deployment. For price cap study areas,
cable broadband deployment was found
to be 3.88% to 68.68%. For A–CAM
study areas, broadband deployment in
areas varied from 0.00% to 89.60%. The
study further attempts to compare price
cap areas with nearby A–CAM areas by
claiming that the differences in the
percentage of cable broadband
deployment between the two sets of
areas are small, ‘‘only 15 percentage
points.’’ This is not small.
93. The study also does not state
whether it limited its analysis of cable
deployment in rate-of-return study areas
to those deployments offering a
minimum of 10/1 Mbps. The study may
have included residential cable
deployments at speeds lower than the
threshold the Commission established
for the price cap competitive market
test. Any such deployments should not
be included in a comparison of price
cap and nearby A–CAM areas.
94. We are also unable to rely on the
conclusions in the Petitioners’ study
since it is based on a misplaced reliance
on inaccuracies inherent in the structure
of the price cap competitive market
test—inaccuracies the Commission
acknowledged when it adopted the
competitive market test in the BDS
Order. In the BDS Order, the
Commission conceded that its countybased competitive market test
unavoidably included a relatively small
number of areas that would be
inappropriately regulated or
inappropriately deregulated. It
explained that the only competitive
market test that would be free of such
inaccuracies would be one that would
be run at a building level—with over a
million buildings with BDS demand, an
administratively unworkable option. It
adopted percentage thresholds for both
prongs of the competitive market test
and employed certain statistical tools to
ensure those thresholds were set at
levels that would minimize
inaccuracies. It further reasoned that
competitive options would become
available for many of these areas in the
short- to medium-term given the
dynamic nature of the BDS marketplace.
95. The Petitioners’ study attempts to
compare A–CAM areas to some of the
very price cap areas most likely to
contain these inaccuracies and to argue
that these inaccuracies justify inclusion
of rural A–CAM areas in the price cap
PO 00000
Frm 00078
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
competitive market test. Extrapolating
from the characterization of peripheral
parts of price cap study areas to A–CAM
areas is likely to exacerbate these
inaccuracies. And unnecessarily so,
since the competitive market test we
adopt offers a simple way of estimating
competition in A–CAM study areas.
Further, these are areas the study
concedes typically lack even the most
basic evidence of BDS competition.
Areas where there is little evidence of
competition are also likely areas where
there is little to no demand for BDS.
96. Given these methodological and
conceptual flaws, we conclude that the
Petitioners’ study fails to establish the
comparability of price cap and nearby
A–CAM areas or provide a reasonable
basis on which to include A–CAM areas
in the price cap competitive market test.
We therefore decline to apply the results
of the price cap competitive market test
to electing carriers’ serving areas.
4. Updating Competitive Market Test
Results
97. Consistent with the BDS Order
competitive market test, we eliminate ex
ante pricing regulation of circuit-based
end user channel terminations at or
below a DS3 level in study areas
deemed competitive by the electing
carriers’ competitive market test. We
direct the Bureau to release a Public
Notice that lists the results of the
competitive market test, and to provide
the information on the Commission’s
website. We will re-run the electing
carriers’ competitive market test every
three years to assess whether any
additional electing carriers’ study areas
meet the 75% threshold. This will
identify any additional electing carriers’
study areas that should be deemed
competitive. We believe a three-year
timeframe balances the need to ensure
the electing carriers’ competitive market
test remains accurate and the
Commission’s desire to avoid disrupting
contracts and burdening carriers with
overly frequent updates. The sunk and
irreversible cost of providing business
data services and deploying a network
represents the biggest barrier to entry for
providers. Once the barrier is overcome,
the marginal cost of operating is low, so
it is unlikely that competition will exit.
Thus, electing carriers’ study areas
deemed competitive will not be
reassessed.
98. To avoid confusion from both
carriers and businesses stemming from
updates from the price cap competitive
market test and the electing carriers
competitive market test, we direct the
Wireline Competition Bureau to re-run
the three-year updates for both the BDS
Order price cap competitive market test,
E:\FR\FM\28DER1.SGM
28DER1
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 248 / Friday, December 28, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
and the electing carriers competitive
market test concurrently. Thus, the
electing carriers’ competitive market test
will initially be re-run in 2020, at the
same time as the BDS Order price cap
competitive market test, to align the
tests’ timing. The re-running of these
tests will coincide with the initial
running of the test for carriers electing
to convert to incentive regulation as of
July 1, 2020. After that, both tests will
be re-run every three years. This
approach will make it easier for
stakeholders to determine the regulatory
status of price cap and rate-of-return
BDS providers since the results will be
published all at once and ease the
burden on Commission resources. The
Bureau shall release a Public Notice that
lists newly competitive counties (for
price cap areas) and study areas (for
electing carriers’ study areas) and shall
also provide this information on the
Commission’s website. As with the BDS
Order competitive market test, parties
may challenge the results of the electing
carriers’ competitive market test by
filing petitions for reconsideration or by
seeking full Commission review through
an application for review.
amozie on DSK3GDR082PROD with RULES
5. Removal of Ex Ante Pricing
Regulation of Electing Carriers’ Lower
Capacity TDM End User Channel
Termination Services
99. We remove ex ante pricing
regulation from electing carriers’ lower
capacity TDM end user channel
termination services offered in study
areas that are deemed competitive by
the electing carriers’ competitive market
test. Such services are presumed to be
subject to sufficient competitive
pressure that removing this layer of
regulation will not result in excessive
rates. Removing this layer of regulation
will reduce unnecessary regulatory
burdens and will enable these carriers to
contribute to BDS competition in their
markets. Such services in such areas
will be relieved of ex ante pricing
regulation and detariffed in the same
manner and with the same transition
provisions as we adopt today for
electing carriers’ packet-based and
higher capacity TDM BDS. As with
packet-based and higher capacity TDM
BDS, we continue to maintain our
oversight over these TDM services
pursuant to sections 201, 202, and 208
of the Act to ensure rates for these
services remain just and reasonable.
Lower capacity TDM transport and end
user channel termination services in
areas deemed noncompetitive by the
competitive market test will continue to
be subject to the incentive regulation
and pricing flexibility we adopt today.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:02 Dec 27, 2018
Jkt 247001
D. Ending Ex Ante Pricing Regulation
for Electing Carriers’ Packet-Based and
Higher Capacity TDM BDS Offerings
100. We conclude that electing
carriers’ packet-based and higher
capacity TDM-based BDS offerings
above a DS3 bandwidth level (which
includes both higher capacity TDM end
user channel terminations and higher
capacity TDM transport) should not be
subject to ex ante pricing regulation and
direct electing carriers to detariff these
services following a transition period.
Our decision to end ex ante pricing
regulation for electing carriers’ packetbased and higher capacity TDM BDS
offerings will facilitate competition for
and deployment of these packet-based
and higher capacity TDM services and
is consistent with the Commission’s
statutory obligation to ensure that rates
are just and reasonable.
101. In the BDS Order, after reviewing
an extensive record, the Commission
found that in price cap markets
nationwide there was no compelling
evidence of incumbent LEC market
power for packet-based and higher
capacity circuit-based BDS. Specifically,
the record demonstrated that demand
for these services was increasing, prices
were declining, and competitive
investment was growing significantly.
The Commission also determined that
the price cap BDS market for packetbased and higher capacity TDM-based
offerings had the characteristics of a
bidding market such that even
competitors that did not have preexisting facilities to serve a potential
customer were nonetheless capable and
willing to bid on requests for proposals
by customers, particularly those with
higher bandwidth needs.
102. The record in this proceeding
lacks the comprehensive and
voluminous data collection available to
the Commission in the price cap BDS
proceeding. But, we recognize that recreating such a similarly detailed data
collection would have been more
difficult for rate-of-return carriers that
receive fixed support, because they have
vastly fewer resources to produce such
information and the benefits of such a
data collection would likely be far
outweighed by its costs. Instead, we
draw parallels where we can from our
conclusions in the BDS Order to inform
our analysis of the record in this
proceeding.
103. In the BDS Order, the fact that
the Commission could not find
compelling evidence to suggest market
power in packet-based and higher
capacity TDM BDS in price cap markets
suggests that the same circumstances
could exist in electing carriers’ BDS
PO 00000
Frm 00079
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
67111
markets. A variety of companies are
investing in next generation networks,
not legacy networks, to compete via
different technologies, which is
consistent with a lack of market power.
Additionally, demand for high speed
BDS exists nationwide. Customer
requests for proposals (RFPs) are not
restricted to price cap areas but seek
proposals for service wherever they
have demand. Thus, the characteristics
of a bidding market that exist in price
cap areas are also likely to be present in
areas served by rate-of-return carriers
that receive fixed support.
104. Relatedly, there is evidence that
the deployment of fiber and sales of
packet-based BDS such as Ethernet
continue to grow substantially and
pervasively. Analysts report that, for the
first time, fiber-connected commercial
building penetration exceeded 50% in
2017—the availability of optical fiber
connectivity to large and medium size
commercial buildings in the U.S.
increased from 49.6% in 2016 to 54.8%
in 2017. In 2018, 98% of our nation’s
elementary and secondary school
districts are served by fiber optic or
other high speed connections. An
analyst’s equipment revenue forecast for
2017 to 2022 projects that Ethernet
access and aggregation will grow 9%
annually. The record in this proceeding
shows that these growth trends are also
apparent in A–CAM carriers’ served
areas. For example, TDS Telecom, Great
Plains, and Consolidated report a fouryear average annual growth rate in
Ethernet sales from December 2014 to
2017 of 10.7%, 15.4%, and 38.3%,
respectively. Over the same periods,
these carriers report declines in legacy
BDS in study areas that were similar to
declines in legacy BDS in price cap
areas. At the same time, consistent with
the Commission’s findings in the BDS
Order, analysts report actual and
forecasted growth in cable revenues,
deployment and market share for small
to national enterprise customers that are
significantly contributing to overall
growth and competition in the BDS
market.
105. There are other reasons to believe
market power for packet-based and
higher capacity TDM business data
services is not present in areas served by
rate-of-return carriers that receive fixed
support. The record shows that large
customers have significant bargaining
leverage over relatively smaller rate-ofreturn carriers that receive fixed
support, limiting what the carriers may
negotiate when bidding on contracts.
For example, ex ante pricing regulation
is unnecessary to protect large and
powerful entities, such as wireless
E:\FR\FM\28DER1.SGM
28DER1
amozie on DSK3GDR082PROD with RULES
67112
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 248 / Friday, December 28, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
carriers, that purchase large quantities
of BDS.
106. The Commission has repeatedly
emphasized its preference for relying on
competition instead of regulation. We
seek to minimize the burdens of
regulation while ensuring that rates and
practices remain just and reasonable.
The Commission previously identified
packet-based services as the ‘‘future of
business data services’’ that are also
‘‘readily scalable.’’ While legacy TDM
BDS is declining, carriers, including
rate-of-return carriers that receive fixed
support, are generally investing
aggressively to deploy high speed
networks in their study areas. The
record shows growing demand for
packet-based and higher capacity TDM
BDS consistent with the Commission’s
findings in the BDS Order, and we find
the record persuasive.
107. Removing ex ante pricing
regulation for packet-based and higher
capacity TDM services, will also
encourage innovation. As the
Commission has previously found, the
potential unintended costs of regulation
are far greater for new services. The
Commission has concluded that ex ante
pricing regulation for these services
should not be imposed even with
‘‘insufficiently robust competition’’
because it would be difficult to
administer such complex regulations.
We are keenly aware of the risk that
heavy-handed regulation could
discourage competitive investment
which would have long-term negative
consequences on competitive
deployment over time.
108. These considerations also apply
to the study areas of rate-of-return
carriers that receive fixed support.
Innovation does not stop at the borders
of a price cap carrier’s study areas. The
record shows that all providers are
accelerating their deployment of next
generation packet-based services in
response to customer demand. We find
that the sensitivity of new and growing
services to imprecise regulation,
particularly rate regulation, is a factor in
areas served by rate-of-return carriers
receiving fixed support as well as areas
served by price cap carriers. For that
reason, consistent with our decision in
the BDS Order, we find that the costs
and potential risks of ex ante pricing
regulation for packet-based and higher
capacity TDM business data services
exceed the benefits and we therefore
eliminate such regulation. This result
provides regulatory parity between
electing carriers and price cap carriers
in their provision of packet-based and
higher capacity TDM business data
services which will benefit consumers.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:02 Dec 27, 2018
Jkt 247001
109. We eliminate ex ante pricing
regulation on the provision of these
services by electing carriers to hasten
deployment of advanced services and
because competition and the size of
purchasers of these services is sufficient
to protect consumers. We affirm,
however, that the Commission retains
authority under sections 201, 202, and
208 of the Act to ensure that packetbased and higher capacity TDM BDS
rates and practices are just, reasonable,
and not unreasonably discriminatory.
The availability of the protections of
sections 201 and 202, and the
importance of the formal fast-track
complaint process of section 208, will
provide sufficient protection against
unreasonable rates and practices in this
increasingly competitive market.
E. Implementation Issues
110. We take a series of additional
steps to ensure electing carriers will be
able fully to implement the BDS
regulatory framework we adopt today,
including adopting deadlines for
implementing incentive regulation,
forbearing from cost assignment and
jurisdictional separations rules,
forbearing from § 54.1305 reporting
requirements, forbearing from section
203 tariffing requirements, allowing
electing carriers to elect to use GAAP
accounting instead of part 32
accounting, and adopting certain
transitional timeframes to facilitate the
detariffing of electing carriers’ packetbased and higher capacity TDM
offerings.
1. Effective Date of Elections
111. We adopt the following
requirements to implement voluntary
incentive regulation for electing carriers.
We adopt the proposal in the NPRM to
make incentive regulation for electing
carriers effective as of July 1, 2019 and
add a second election date option for
carriers that will be effective July 1,
2020. We agree with Petitioners that a
January 1, 2019 effective date would be
the least burdensome for carriers
because cost studies are performed on a
calendar year basis and ‘‘would benefit
customers and competition alike.’’
However, a January 1, 2019 effective
date is not practicable because the rules
adopted in this Order contain new or
modified information collection
requirements triggering Paperwork
Reduction Act review by the Office of
Management and Budget (OMB), a
process which takes approximately five
months to complete. A January 1, 2019
effective date would also provide
insufficient time for electing carriers in
the traffic-sensitive NECA pool to
remove their BDS offerings from the
PO 00000
Frm 00080
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
pool. Our rules require that annual
access charge tariff filings be filed with
a scheduled effective date of July 1. As
such, a July 1 effective date is consistent
with current tariffing procedures and
will simplify the implementation of the
changes adopted in this Order.
112. Similarly, we adopt July 1 as the
effective date for any future election.
July 1 is the most efficient effective date
because allowing carriers accepting
future offers of A–CAM support to set
their initial rates on another date would
add cost and complexity to the process.
Petitioners suggest using a January 1
effective date but doing so would
require an electing carrier to make an
additional tariff filing beyond the
required July 1 annual filing. NECA, and
the Commission, would have to
undertake their associated review of the
tariff, and NECA would be required to
conduct its mid-year cost studies for the
remaining pool members, calculate
support for existing members, reband,
and undertake other steps it would not
do otherwise. Additionally, a January 1
effective date would be based on the
previous year’s cost study. Relying on
year-old data would undermine the
validity of the tariff filings. It is possible
that an electing carrier could prepare a
cost study for only a portion of the
current year and multiply the results of
the study to estimate a year’s data, but
that approach creates additional
burdens for carriers, complicates
NECA’s implementation, and would
still not represent a fully accurate
picture of the carrier’s costs and
demand. When considered together, we
find that using July 1 as a deadline for
setting initial rates in any future A–
CAM offer is the most efficient and
feasible approach.
113. Electing carriers currently in the
NECA pool are required to notify NECA
by March 1, 2019 that they will not
participate in the upcoming NECA
traffic-sensitive tariff for their BDS
offerings consistent with § 69.3 of our
rules. Similarly, NECA pool carriers that
elect to convert to incentive regulation
effective July 1, 2020, must notify NECA
that they will not participate in the
NECA traffic-sensitive pool for BDS
offerings by March 1, 2020. NECA pool
carriers that accept future offers of A–
CAM support and elect the incentive
regulation framework we adopt today or
otherwise transition away from legacy
support mechanisms must notify NECA
by March 1 of their election year
consistent with § 69.3. The Commission
proposed requiring electing carriers to
provide the Bureau with 120 days’
notice of their election to facilitate
implementation of the revised tariffs but
we now agree with Petitioners that
E:\FR\FM\28DER1.SGM
28DER1
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 248 / Friday, December 28, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
amozie on DSK3GDR082PROD with RULES
opposed granting so much advanced
notice. Accordingly, we require electing
carriers electing to convert to incentive
regulation effective July 1, 2019 to
provide the Bureau with notice of their
election by May 1, 2019. Carriers that
elect our second incentive regulation
option date, effective July 1, 2020, must
notify the Bureau by May 1, 2020.
Carriers that accept future offers of A–
CAM support and carriers that
otherwise transition away from legacy
support mechanisms must provide
notice of their election or transition to
the Bureau by May 1 of the year of
election or transition. Electing carriers
that choose to update their separations
category relationships pursuant to this
Order shall include information to that
effect in these notices to NECA and the
Bureau.
2. Implementing Forbearance
114. As part of implementing our new
regulatory framework for electing
carriers’ BDS, we grant forbearance from
certain existing Commission rules and
statutory requirements, including our
tariffing obligations for electing carriers’
packet-based and higher capacity (i.e.,
above a DS3 bandwidth level) TDM
business data services and lower
capacity TDM end user channel
termination services in study areas
deemed competitive; our Cost
Assignment Rules; and our § 54.1305
reporting requirements, for electing
carriers’ lower capacity (i.e., at or below
a DS3 bandwidth level) TDM transport
and end user channel termination
services. Forbearance will be effective
July 1, 2019 for carriers electing
incentive regulation of their business
data services as of July 1, 2019, and July
1, 2020 for carrier’s electing incentive
regulation as of July 1, 2020. Section 10
of the Act requires that the Commission
forbear from applying any provision of
the Act, or any of the Commission’s
regulations, if the Commission
determines that: (1) Enforcement of the
provision or regulation is not necessary
to ensure that a telecommunications
carrier’s ‘‘charges, practices,
classifications or regulations’’ are ‘‘just
and reasonable and are not unjustly or
unreasonably discriminatory,’’ (2)
enforcement of the provision or
regulation is ‘‘not necessary for the
protection of consumers,’’ and (3)
forbearance is consistent with the public
interest. In making the public interest
determination, the Commission must
also consider, pursuant to section 10(b),
‘‘whether forbearance from enforcing
the provision or regulation will promote
competitive market conditions.’’ We
find that granting forbearance in these
instances will meet the statutory
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:02 Dec 27, 2018
Jkt 247001
forbearance requirements and will
facilitate electing carriers’ transition to
incentive regulation, putting them on a
footing similar to that of price cap
carriers in their provision of BDS.
a. Forbearance from Tariffing
Requirements for Packet-Based and
Higher Capacity TDM Services and
Lower Capacity TDM End User Channel
Terminations in Study Areas Deemed
Competitive
115. In order to effectuate our lighttouch regulatory framework for packetbased and higher capacity TDM
business data services above the DS3
bandwidth level, we grant forbearance,
pursuant to section 10 of the Act, from
section 203 tariffing requirements for
these services offered by electing
carriers. In addition, we grant
forbearance for lower capacity TDM end
user channel terminations offered in
electing carriers’ study areas deemed
competitive by the competitive market
test. Forbearance from section 203
tariffing obligations is warranted under
section 10 of the Act, is consistent with
our finding that electing carriers lack
market power in packet-based and
higher capacity TDM business data
services, and end user channel
terminations in study areas deemed
competitive by the competitive market
test, and will enhance competition and
deployment of these next generation
services.
116. Forbearance from section 203
tariffing requirements for packet-based
and higher capacity TDM BDS offerings
above the DS3 bandwidth level, and for
lower capacity TDM end user channel
terminations in study areas deemed
competitive by the competitive market
test, satisfies all three prongs of the
forbearance analysis. First, pursuant to
section 10(a)(1), we conclude in the
context of growing demand for high
speed services detariffing these services
will promote competitive market
conditions, which will result in lower
prices and better services, thus ensuring
that electing carriers’ relevant charges,
practices, classifications, and
regulations are just and reasonable and
not unreasonably discriminatory.
Similarly, the existence of demonstrated
competition for end user channel
terminations in markets deemed
competitive will restrain
anticompetitive behavior, lower prices,
increase innovation, and protect
consumers from charges, practices,
classifications, and regulations that are
not just and reasonable and
unreasonably discriminatory.
Competition will serve to limit electing
carriers’ behavior. Absent forbearance,
as commenters argue, Commission
PO 00000
Frm 00081
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
67113
regulation could have the inverse effect
and harm competition and network
deployment.
117. We also conclude that, pursuant
to section 10(a)(2), enforcement of our
tariffing requirements for these services
is ‘‘not necessary for the protection of
consumers.’’ Indeed, by encouraging
competition, granting forbearance from
tariffing of these services will benefit
consumers by increasing deployment
and lowering cost. Competition among
carriers and the roll-out of next
generation packet-based and higher
capacity TDM circuit-based BDS will
lower prices and provide new services.
In study areas deemed competitive,
competition will also protect
consumers. The Commission has
previously found that tariffs were
originally required to protect consumers
but they are unnecessary if a provider
faces competitive pressures. If an
electing carrier harms a consumer the
consumer can switch to other
competitors present in the study area.
This threat protects consumers. Of
course, in the event that there is risk of
consumer harm, sections 201, 202, and
208 remain applicable to enforce the
Commission’s rules and protect
consumers’ welfare. Based on
competition in the market and our
statutory mandate as a backstop, we find
that section 203 is not necessary to
protect consumers in electing carriers’
packet-based and higher capacity TDM
markets, and for lower capacity TDM
end user channel termination in study
areas deemed competitive by the
electing carriers’ competitive market
test.
118. Third, we conclude that
forbearance from these statutory and
regulatory requirements is in the public
interest. Forbearance from the tariffing
requirement for these packet-based and
higher capacity TDM services and for
lower capacity TDM end user channel
terminations in markets deemed
competitive will promote competition,
reduce compliance costs, increase
investment and innovation, and
facilitate the technology transitions. We
therefore find that application of section
203 is not necessary under sections
10(a)(1) and 10(a)(2), and is in the
public interest, consistent with sections
10(a)(3) and 10(b).
b. Cost Assignment Rules Forbearance
119. In light of our decision to relieve
electing carriers of the obligation to
conduct cost studies, we grant electing
carriers forbearance, pursuant to section
10 of the Act, from the Commission’s
Cost Assignment Rules for their BDS
services, although we grant forbearance
for their lower capacity (i.e., at or below
E:\FR\FM\28DER1.SGM
28DER1
amozie on DSK3GDR082PROD with RULES
67114
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 248 / Friday, December 28, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
a DS3 bandwidth level) TDM transport
and end user channel termination
services after they have set initial rates
for those offerings. Additionally,
electing carriers that participate in the
NECA pool must conduct cost studies
for the calendar year prior to their
election and the first half of the year of
their election to comply with their pool
settlement requirements.
120. Background. The Cost
Assignment Rules generally require
carriers to assign costs to build and
maintain the network and revenues
from services provided to specific
categories. Categories include
nonregulated or regulated service, the
intrastate or interstate jurisdiction, and
specific access services, such as local
switching or common line. The Cost
Assignment Rules also govern the
accounting treatment of transactions
between a carrier and its affiliate, such
as the sale or transfer of assets between
regulated and nonregulated affiliates. In
addition, the rules include certain
reporting requirements, which depend
on the availability of data produced by
the Cost Assignment Rules.
121. As part of the regulatory
accounting process, carriers first record
their costs, including investments and
expenses, into various accounts in
accordance with the Uniform System of
Accounts (USOA) prescribed by part 32
of the Commission’s rules. Next, using
the Cost Assignment Rules in part 64,
carriers directly assign, or allocate if
direct assignment is not possible, the
costs and revenues associated with their
regulated and nonregulated activities.
After costs and revenues are divided
between those that are regulated and
nonregulated, interstate and intrastate
costs and revenues are separated as
provided in part 36. Federal and state
regulatory jurisdictions apply their own
ratemaking processes to the amounts
assigned to each jurisdiction. Finally,
the access charge rules in part 69
require carriers to separate regulated
interstate costs into interexchange costs
and access costs, and then apportion the
latter among access categories or
elements.
122. The Commission adopted the
Cost Assignment Rules to help ensure
that carriers charge just and reasonable
rates for the services they provide. The
Commission adopted the Cost
Assignment Rules prior to 1991 when
all incumbent LECs were subject to rateof-return regulation, so that it could set
rates that allowed carriers to recover
their costs and earn a specific return on
their regulated investment.
Subsequently, the Commission moved
away from rate-of-return regulation for
the larger incumbent LECs. In its place,
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:02 Dec 27, 2018
Jkt 247001
it adopted price cap regulation, a form
of incentive regulation that seeks to
‘‘harness the profit-making incentives
common to all businesses to produce a
set of outcomes that advance the public
interest goals of just, reasonable, and
nondiscriminatory rates, as well as a
communications system that offers
innovative, high quality services.’’
123. In 2008, the Commission granted
AT&T conditional forbearance from the
Cost Assignment Rules. The
Commission conditioned the
forbearance on, among other things,
requiring AT&T to retain part 32
Uniform System of Accounts data and
submit a compliance plan describing in
detail how it would fulfill its statutory
and regulatory requirements. The
Commission granted similar conditional
forbearance from the Cost Assignment
Rules to Verizon and Qwest.
Subsequently, Qwest, Verizon, and
AT&T obtained conditional forbearance
from certain financial reporting
requirements that relied on the Cost
Assignment Rules. In 2013, the
Commission extended the conditional
forbearance granted the three carriers to
all price cap carriers.
124. In the Part 32 Order, 82 FR
20833, May 4, 2017, the Commission
terminated the conditions that the
Commission placed on a variety of
carriers granted forbearance from our
Cost Assignment Rules. The
Commission noted that forbearance was
expressly premised on the continued
availability of part 32 accounting data
and the filing of compliance plans
consistent with that condition. The
Commission determined that continuing
to maintain these costly requirements
on the speculation that at some point
the Commission might do something
with them failed any cost-benefit
analysis.
125. Discussion. We find that
applying the Cost Assignment Rules to
electing carriers is no longer necessary
to ensure that charges and practices are
just, reasonable, and not unjustly or
unreasonably discriminatory; to protect
consumers; or to protect the public
interest. Much of the reasoning in the
Commission’s earlier decisions to grant
price cap LECs forbearance from the
Cost Assignment Rules applies equally
to rate-of-return carriers receiving fixed
support that elect incentive regulation.
With respect to ensuring charges,
practices, classifications, and
regulations are just and reasonable and
not unjustly or unreasonably
discriminatory, as discussed above, the
Cost Assignment Rules were developed
when the incumbent LECs’ interstate
rates and many of their intrastate rates
were set under rate-based, cost-of-
PO 00000
Frm 00082
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
service regulation. Because the
incentive regulation we adopt severs for
BDS the direct link between regulated
costs and prices just as price cap
regulation did, a carrier is not able
automatically to recoup misallocated
nonregulated costs by raising BDS rates,
thus reducing incentives to shift
nonregulated costs to regulated services.
To the extent incentives remain, we find
our positive experience with the
waivers of the all-or-nothing rule
provides confidence that the additional
costs of maintaining the Cost
Assignment Rules outweighs any
possible benefit of maintaining them.
There is no reason to impose on electing
carriers cost assignment requirements
that were ‘‘designed to parallel the level
of detail in the cost-of-service
calculations that LECs performed to
develop their rates for interstate access
services.’’ Moreover, if the need arises
for cost data from electing carriers, we
find there are less costly ways to meet
that need.
126. With respect to the second prong
of the forbearance test, protecting
consumers, the Commission adopted the
Cost Assignment Rules in part to help
protect consumers from improper crosssubsidization of competitive services
provided on an integrated basis with
noncompetitive services by dominant
providers with individual market
power. Because the rates for regulated
services and the determination of the
level of universal service support are no
longer tied to accounting costs, electing
carriers will have no incentive to shift
costs between regulated and
nonregulated services, or to services
receiving universal service support, thus
the consumer protection issues that
animate the Cost Assignment Rules are
not relevant for electing carriers.
127. We also find that forbearing from
the Cost Assignment Rules for electing
carriers is in the public interest. Because
neither rates nor universal service
support will be cost-based for electing
carriers, relieving electing carriers of the
expense of compliance with the Cost
Assignment Rules will allow electing
carriers to offer more competitive rates
and more innovative service, thus
furthering the public interest.
128. Finally, section 10(b) requires us
to consider, as part of our analysis of the
public interest prong, whether
forbearance will promote competitive
market conditions. We agree with
Petitioners, TDS Telecom and other
commenters that contend that
forbearance will enhance competition.
Eliminating unnecessary regulation will
generally reduce electing carriers’ costs
and, in turn, benefit consumers through
lower rates and/or more vibrant
E:\FR\FM\28DER1.SGM
28DER1
amozie on DSK3GDR082PROD with RULES
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 248 / Friday, December 28, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
competitive offerings. Because other
providers of similar services are not
subject to the rules, it also promotes
competition by providing a more level
playing field. Moreover, as noted above,
we find that sufficient protections
remain in place to prevent anticompetitive cross-subsidization.
129. We note that there still may be
instances in which an electing carrier
seeks some other type of relief from the
Commission that requires supporting
cost assignment data. In such instances,
the burden is on the carrier to retain
data sufficient to make the required
showing to the Commission in support
of such a carrier-initiated request.
130. As part of our forbearance from
the Cost Assignment Rules, we also
forbear from the NECA data reporting
requirement in § 54.1305 of our rules
and, by extension, from the related
requirement to update information
shared with NECA. Under the
Commission’s rules, incumbent LECs
are required to report unseparated loop
cost data to NECA annually. Price cap
carriers and their affiliates have been
exempt from this obligation since the
Commission adopted the USF/ICC
Transformation Order and various price
cap cost assignment forbearance orders.
This reporting requirement depends on
the availability of data produced by the
Cost Assignment Rules. As part of the
forbearance adopted in this Order, we
cease to require data that would
otherwise be reported as part of a cost
study. Retaining this obligation is thus
inconsistent with our grant of
forbearance and is inconsistent with
past price cap carrier forbearance grants.
Retaining this obligation would also
eliminate one of the core incentives for
rate-of-return carriers to elect incentive
regulation—cost savings from the
elimination of the obligation to
undertake cost studies.
131. Granting forbearance from NECA
reporting requirements satisfies all three
prongs of the forbearance analysis. The
NECA data collection requirement is not
necessary to ensure that carrier charges
and practices are just and reasonable, as
evidenced by the fact that price cap
carriers have been operating without
NECA reporting for nearly six years
without issue. While no longer
including electing carriers’ data in the
calculation of the national average cost
per loop will affect that calculation, we
do not think that any impact it may
have outweighs the benefits of removing
these reporting obligations. Since the
very goal of incentive regulation is to
disconnect cost and rates to promote
competition in the marketplace,
reporting cost data to NECA is also
unnecessary to protect consumers.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:02 Dec 27, 2018
Jkt 247001
Additionally, because forbearance from
enforcing these rules is necessary to
obtain the benefit of reducing
unnecessary regulatory compliance
costs this Order seeks, forbearance is
consistent with the public interest.
Retaining the data collection and
reporting requirements of §§ 54.1305
and 54.1306 would force electing
carriers to continue to perform annual
cost studies and would thus eliminate
one of the chief sources of cost savings
of this Order. Forbearing from these
requirements will promote competition
by allowing these resources to be
redirected to increase network
investment and to accelerate the
technology transition from legacy
circuit-based services to packet-based
services such as Ethernet.
3. GAAP Accounting
132. We allow electing carriers the
option of using generally accepted
accounting principles (GAAP) for
keeping their accounts. The only
commenters that oppose allowing
electing carriers to use GAAP
accounting incorrectly argue that for
electing carriers part 32, cost studies
and other protections are necessary
because ‘‘these electing carriers would
continue to have certain of their
interstate services under rate-of-return.’’
In fact, as explained by Petitioners, all
of the interstate telecommunications
services offered by electing carriers will
either be (1) subject to incentive
regulation, (2) not subject to ex ante
pricing regulation, or (3) capped and
transitioning downward by the terms of
the rate-of-return intercarrier
compensation rules. Thus, there is no
significant reason to continue to
maintain burdensome part 32
accounting for electing carriers.
133. The Commission recently revised
its part 32 accounting rules to allow
price cap LECs to elect to use GAAP in
recording and reporting their financial
data, subject to two targeted accounting
requirements. We subject electing
carriers that choose to use GAAP
accounting to the same data
provisioning requirements as price cap
carriers, including the requirements
relating to the calculation of pole
attachment rates. Electing carriers may
either (a) calculate an Implementation
Rate Difference between the attachment
rates calculated by the carrier under the
Uniform System of Accounts (USOA)
and under GAAP as of the last full year
preceding the carrier’s initial opting-out
of part 32 USOA accounting
requirements; or (b) comply with GAAP
accounting for all purposes other than
those associated with setting pole
attachment rates while continuing to
PO 00000
Frm 00083
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
67115
use the part 32 accounts and procedures
necessary to establish and evaluate pole
attachment rates. Electing carriers must
adjust their annually computed GAAPbased rates by the Implementation Rate
Difference for a period of 12 years after
the election. This will free electing
carriers from having to maintain two
sets of books: one for financial reporting
purposes consistent with GAAP and one
for regulatory reporting purposes
consistent with the accounting
requirements of part 32.
4. Transitions
134. Consistent with our actions in
the BDS Order, our detariffing actions in
this Order for electing carriers’ study
areas will be mandatory after a
transition that will provide electing
carriers sufficient time to adapt their
business data services operations to a
detariffing regime.
135. The transition period will begin
on the date incentive regulation
becomes effective for electing carriers,
either July 1, 2019 or July 1, 2020, and
will end thirty-six (36) months
thereafter, a period that we find
sufficient for electing carriers to adapt to
a detariffing regime. In addition, for six
(6) months following the date incentive
regulation becomes effective, we require
electing carriers to freeze the tariffed
rates for their business data services that
are no longer subject to ex ante pricing
regulation, including lower speed TDM
end user channel terminations in newly
deregulated study areas, provided those
services remain tariffed. These
transition mechanisms will ensure that
small businesses and other purchasers
have time to adjust to the new
regulatory framework we adopt.
136. Similarly, carriers electing
incentive regulation in connection with
a subsequent offer of A–CAM support,
or carriers that the Commission
otherwise transitions away from legacy
support mechanisms must detariff the
relevant business data services within
thirty-six (36) months of the date on
which their incentive-based rates take
effect or their transition away from
legacy support mechanisms becomes
effective. Further, for six (6) months
following such dates, such carriers will
be required to freeze their tariffed rates
for BDS that are no longer subject to ex
ante pricing regulation, provided those
rates remain tariffed.
137. Tariffing for these services will
be permissive during the transition—we
will accept new tariffs and revisions to
existing tariffs for the affected services
during this time period. Electing carriers
may also detariff during the transition.
Apart from the rate freeze noted above,
carriers will no longer be required to
E:\FR\FM\28DER1.SGM
28DER1
67116
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 248 / Friday, December 28, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
comply with ex ante pricing regulation
for these services. Once the rules
adopted in this Order are effective,
carriers that wish to continue filing
tariffs under the permissive detariffing
regime are free to modify such tariffs to
reflect the new regulatory structure
outlined in this Order for the affected
services. This will allow carriers to be
more competitive and introduce new
business data services as they adapt to
detariffing.
138. Electing carriers may remove the
relevant portions of their tariffs for the
affected services at any time during the
transition, and the rate freeze does not
apply to services that are no longer
tariffed. Electing carriers may not file or
maintain any interstate tariffs for
affected business data services once the
transition ends. This will prevent
electing carriers from obtaining
‘‘deemed lawful’’ status for tariff filings
that are not accompanied by cost
support and invoking the filed-rate
doctrine in contractual disputes with
customers. Business data service
providers will also be prevented from
picking and choosing when they are
able to invoke the protections of tariffs.
139. We do not intend our actions to
disturb existing contractual or other
long-term arrangements—a contract
tariff remains a contract even if it is no
longer tariffed. As we stated in the BDS
Order, contract tariffs, term and volume
discount plans, and individual circuit
plans do not become void upon
detariffing. All carriers are to act in good
faith to develop solutions to ensure rates
remain just and reasonable.
amozie on DSK3GDR082PROD with RULES
III. Other Rule Changes
140. We adopt several other rule
changes which can be found set out
below. These rule changes include
changes arising from this Order as well
as corrections to inaccuracies in our
current rules. Thus, we change (1) the
cross reference to § 61.3(aa) in
§ 51.903(g) to § 61.3(bb), (2) the cross
reference to § 61.3(ee) in § 61.41(d) to
§ 61.3(ff), (3) the cross reference
§ 61.3(x) in § 69.114 to § 61.3(ff), and (4)
the cross reference to § 69.801(g) in
§ 69.805(a) to § 69.801(h). These cross
references have been rendered
inaccurate because of changes in the
definitions contained in § 61.3.
IV. Final Regulatory Flexibility
Analysis
141. As required by the Regulatory by
the Regulatory Flexibility Act of 1980,
as amended (RFA) an Initial Regulatory
Flexibility Analysis (IRFA) was
incorporated into the Notice of
Proposed Rulemaking (NPRM) for the
rate-of-return business data services
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:02 Dec 27, 2018
Jkt 247001
(BDS) proceeding. The Commission
sought written public comment on the
proposals in the NPRM, including
comment on the IRFA. The Commission
received no comments on the IRFA.
Because the Commission amends its
rules in this Report and Order, the
Commission has included this Final
Regulatory Flexibility Analysis (FRFA).
This present FRFA conforms to the
RFA.
A. Need for, and Objectives of, the Rules
142. In the NPRM, the Commission
proposed to adopt a form of incentive
regulation for the provision of business
data services by rate-of-return carriers
receiving fixed universal service
support, conduct a market analysis to
evaluate the characteristics of BDS
markets served by rate-of-return carriers
receiving fixed support, and adopt a
new lighter touch regulatory framework
for these carriers’ BDS that in most
respects parallels the framework
recently adopted for price cap carriers
in the BDS Order. This Order provides
a new framework for BDS offered by
rate-of-return carriers that receive fixed
support that minimizes unnecessary
regulatory burdens on certain rate-ofreturn carriers and allows market forces
to foster appropriate incentives for these
carriers to be efficient, to innovate and
to compete.
143. In this Order, the Commission
takes the next step in a series of steps
to encourage carriers to move from rateof-return to incentive regulation, and to
remove ex ante pricing regulation where
competitive conditions justify doing so.
This Order focuses on allowing rate-ofreturn carriers that currently receive
fixed high-cost universal service
support to voluntarily elect to transition
out of rate-of-return regulation for their
BDS offerings. In so doing, the
Commission amends its rules to allow
such carriers to move their lower
capacity time division multiplexing
(TDM) circuit-based transport and end
user channel termination offerings to
incentive regulation while providing a
path for those carriers that elect our new
framework (electing carriers) to
demonstrate that their lower capacity
circuit-based end user channel
termination offerings are competitive,
and therefore should not be subject to ex
ante pricing regulation. We also remove
ex ante pricing regulation from electing
carriers’ higher capacity circuit-based
and their packet-based BDS offerings.
144. Allowing rate-of-return carriers
that receive fixed support to move their
BDS offerings away from rate-of-return
regulation will help drive competition
for BDS offerings in the communities
served by those carriers. It will also
PO 00000
Frm 00084
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
reduce unnecessary regulatory burdens
faced by electing carriers. They will no
longer be required to provide cost-based
justification for their BDS rates and will
therefore no longer need to conduct
annual cost studies to justify those rates.
They will also no longer be required to
file tariffs for their packed-based and
higher capacity TDM-based end user
channel terminations offerings in areas
deemed competitive. The regulatory
burdens on electing carriers, most of
which are small entities, will be vastly
reduced.
145. We take these steps while
affirming our core statutory obligations
pursuant to sections 201, 202, and 208
of the Communications Act to ensure
that the rates and practices of these
carriers’ BDS remain just, reasonable
and not unreasonably discriminatory.
Collectively, these actions will
streamline regulation, and spur entry,
investment, innovation, and
competition in the affected BDS markets
to the benefit of businesses and other
institutional users that rely on these
services.
B. Summary of Significant Issues Raised
by Public Comments in Response to the
IRFA
146. The Commission did not receive
comments specifically addressing the
rules and policies proposed in the IRFA.
C. Response to Comments by the Chief
Counsel for Advocacy of the Small
Business Administration
147. The Chief Counsel did not file
any comments in response to this
proceeding.
D. Description and Estimate of the
Number of Small Entities to Which the
Rules Will Apply
148. The RFA directs agencies to
provide a description of, and where
feasible, an estimate of the number of
small entities that may be affected by
the proposed rules, if adopted. The RFA
generally defines the term ‘‘small
entity’’ as having the same meaning as
the terms ‘‘small business,’’ ‘‘small
organization,’’ and ‘‘small governmental
jurisdiction.’’ In addition, the term
‘‘small business’’ has the same meaning
as the term ‘‘small-business concern’’
under the Small Business Act. A smallbusiness concern’’ is one which: (1) Is
independently owned and operated; (2)
is not dominant in its field of operation;
and (3) satisfies any additional criteria
established by the Small Business
Administration (SBA).
1. Total Small Entities
149. Our proposed action, if
implemented, may, over time, affect
E:\FR\FM\28DER1.SGM
28DER1
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 248 / Friday, December 28, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
small entities that are not easily
categorized at present. We therefore
describe here, at the outset, three
comprehensive, statutory small entity
size standards. First, as of 2013, the SBA
estimates there are an estimated 28.8
million small businesses nationwide—
comprising some 99.9% of all
businesses. In addition, a ‘‘small
organization’’ is generally ‘‘any not-forprofit enterprise which is independently
owned and operated and is not
dominant in its field.’’ Nationwide, as of
2007, there were approximately
1,621,315 small organizations. Finally,
the term ‘‘small governmental
jurisdiction’’ is defined generally as
‘‘governments of cities, towns,
townships, villages, school districts, or
special districts, with a population of
less than fifty thousand.’’ Census
Bureau data for 2012 indicate that there
were 90,056 local governmental
jurisdictions in the United States. We
estimate that, of this total, as many as
89,195 entities may qualify as ‘‘small
governmental jurisdictions.’’ Thus, we
estimate that most governmental
jurisdictions are small.
amozie on DSK3GDR082PROD with RULES
2. Broadband internet Access Service
Providers
150. internet Service Providers
(Broadband). Broadband internet
service providers include wired (e.g.,
cable, DSL) and VoIP service providers
using their own operated wired
telecommunications infrastructure fall
in the category of Wired
Telecommunication Carriers. Wired
Telecommunications Carriers are
comprised of establishments primarily
engaged in operating and/or providing
access to transmission facilities and
infrastructure that they own and/or
lease for the transmission of voice, data,
text, sound, and video using wired
telecommunications networks.
Transmission facilities may be based on
a single technology or a combination of
technologies. The SBA size standard for
this category classifies a business as
small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees.
U.S. Census data for 2012 show that
there were 3,117 firms that operated that
year. Of this total, 3,083 operated with
fewer than 1,000 employees.
Consequently, under this size standard
the majority of firms in this industry can
be considered small.
3. Wireline Providers
151. Wired Telecommunications
Carriers. The U.S. Census Bureau
defines this industry as ‘‘establishments
primarily engaged in operating and/or
providing access to transmission
facilities and infrastructure that they
own and/or lease for the transmission of
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:02 Dec 27, 2018
Jkt 247001
voice, data, text, sound, and video using
wired communications networks.
Transmission facilities may be based on
a single technology or a combination of
technologies. Establishments in this
industry use the wired
telecommunications network facilities
that they operate to provide a variety of
services, such as wired telephony
services, including VoIP services, wired
(cable) audio and video programming
distribution, and wired broadband
internet services. By exception,
establishments providing satellite
television distribution services using
facilities and infrastructure that they
operate are included in this industry.’’
The SBA has developed a small
business size standard for Wired
Telecommunications Carriers, which
consists of all such companies having
1,500 or fewer employees. Census data
for 2012 show that there were 3,117
firms that operated that year. Of this
total, 3,083 operated with fewer than
1,000 employees. Thus, under this size
standard, the majority of firms in this
industry can be considered small.
152. Incumbent Local Exchange
Carriers (Incumbent LECs). Neither the
Commission nor the SBA has developed
a small business size standard
specifically for incumbent LEC services.
The closest applicable size standard
under SBA rules is for the category
Wired Telecommunications Carriers as
defined above. Under that size standard,
such a business is small if it has 1,500
or fewer employees. According to
Commission data, 3,117 firms operated
in that year. Of this total, 3,083 operated
with fewer than 1,000 employees.
Consequently, the Commission
estimates that most providers of
incumbent local exchange service are
small businesses that may be affected by
the rules and policies adopted. A total
of 1,307 firms reported that they were
incumbent local exchange service
providers. Of this total, an estimated
1,006 have 1,500 or fewer employees.
153. Competitive Local Exchange
Carriers (Competitive LECs),
Competitive Access Providers (CAPs),
Shared-Tenant Service Providers, and
Other Local Service Providers. Neither
the Commission nor the SBA has
developed a small business size
standard specifically for these service
providers. The appropriate NAICS Code
category is Wired Telecommunications
Carriers, as defined above. Under that
size standard, such a business is small
if it has 1,500 or fewer employees. U.S.
Census data for 2012 indicate that 3,117
firms operated during that year. Of that
number, 3,083 operated with fewer than
1,000 employees. Based on this data, the
Commission concludes that the majority
PO 00000
Frm 00085
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
67117
of Competitive LECS, CAPs, SharedTenant Service Providers, and Other
Local Service Providers, are small
entities. According to Commission data,
1,442 carriers reported that they were
engaged in the provision of either
competitive local exchange services or
competitive access provider services. Of
these 1,442 carriers, an estimated 1,256
have 1,500 or fewer employees. In
addition, 17 carriers have reported that
they are Shared-Tenant Service
Providers, and all 17 are estimated to
have 1,500 or fewer employees. Also, 72
carriers have reported that they are
Other Local Service Providers. Of this
total, 70 have 1,500 or fewer employees.
Consequently, based on internally
researched FCC data, the Commission
estimates that most providers of
competitive local exchange service,
competitive access providers, SharedTenant Service Providers, and Other
Local Service Providers are small
entities.
154. We have included small
incumbent LECs in this present RFA
analysis. As noted above, a ‘‘small
business’’ under the RFA is one that,
inter alia, meets the pertinent small
business size standard (e.g., a telephone
communications business having 1,500
or fewer employees), and ‘‘is not
dominant in its field of operation.’’ The
SBA’s Office of Advocacy contends that,
for RFA purposes, small incumbent
LECs are not dominant in their field of
operation because any such dominance
is not ‘‘national’’ in scope. We have
therefore included small incumbent
LECs in this RFA analysis, although we
emphasize that this RFA action has no
effect on Commission analyses and
determinations in other, non-RFA
contexts.
155. Interexchange Carriers (IXCs).
Neither the Commission nor the SBA
has developed a definition for
Interexchange Carriers. The closest
NAICS Code category is Wired
Telecommunications Carriers as defined
above. The applicable size standard
under SBA rules is that such a business
is small if it has 1,500 or fewer
employees. U.S. Census data for 2012
indicates that 3,117 firms operated
during that year. Of that number, 3,083
operated with fewer than 1,000
employees. According to internally
developed Commission data, 359
companies reported that their primary
telecommunications service activity was
the provision of interexchange services.
Of this total, an estimated 317 have
1,500 or fewer employees.
Consequently, the Commission
estimates that the majority of IXCs are
small entities that may be affected by
our rules.
E:\FR\FM\28DER1.SGM
28DER1
amozie on DSK3GDR082PROD with RULES
67118
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 248 / Friday, December 28, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
156. Local Resellers. The SBA has
developed a small business size
standard for the category of
Telecommunications Resellers. The
Telecommunications Resellers industry
comprises establishments engaged in
purchasing access and network capacity
from owners and operators of
telecommunications networks and
reselling wired and wireless
telecommunications services (except
satellite) to businesses and households.
Establishments in this industry resell
telecommunications; they do not
operate transmission facilities and
infrastructure. Mobile virtual network
operators (MVNOs) are included in this
industry. Under that size standard, such
a business is small if it has 1,500 or
fewer employees. Census data for 2012
show that 1,341 firms provided resale
services during that year. Of that
number, all operated with fewer than
1,000 employees. Thus, under this
category and the associated small
business size standard, the majority of
these prepaid calling card providers can
be considered small entities.
157. Toll Resellers. The Commission
has not developed a definition for Toll
Resellers. The closest NAICS Code
Category is Telecommunications
Resellers. The Telecommunications
Resellers industry comprises
establishments engaged in purchasing
access and network capacity from
owners and operators of
telecommunications networks and
reselling wired and wireless
telecommunications services (except
satellite) to businesses and households.
Establishments in this industry resell
telecommunications; they do not
operate transmission facilities and
infrastructure. Mobile virtual network
operators (MVNOs) are included in this
industry. The SBA has developed a
small business size standard for the
category of Telecommunications
Resellers. Under that size standard, such
a business is small if it has 1,500 or
fewer employees. Census data for 2012
show that 1,341 firms provided resale
services during that year. Of that
number, 1,341 operated with fewer than
1,000 employees. Thus, under this
category and the associated small
business size standard, the majority of
these resellers can be considered small
entities. According to Commission data,
881 carriers have reported that they are
engaged in the provision of toll resale
services. Of this total, an estimated 857
have 1,500 or fewer employees.
Consequently, the Commission
estimates that the majority of toll
resellers are small entities.
158. Other Toll Carriers. Neither the
Commission nor the SBA has developed
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:02 Dec 27, 2018
Jkt 247001
a definition for small businesses
specifically applicable to Other Toll
Carriers. This category includes toll
carriers that do not fall within the
categories of interexchange carriers,
operator service providers, prepaid
calling card providers, satellite service
carriers, or toll resellers. The closest
applicable NAICS Code category is for
Wired Telecommunications Carriers as
defined above. Under the applicable
SBA size standard, such a business is
small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees.
Census data for 2012 show that there
were 3,117 firms that operated that year.
Of this total, 3,083 operated with fewer
than 1,000 employees. Thus, under this
category and the associated small
business size standard, the majority of
Other Toll Carriers can be considered
small. According to internally
developed Commission data, 284
companies reported that their primary
telecommunications service activity was
the provision of other toll carriage. Of
these, an estimated 279 have 1,500 or
fewer employees. Consequently, the
Commission estimates that most Other
Toll Carriers are small entities that may
be affected by rules adopted pursuant to
the Order.
159. Operator Service Providers
(OSPs). Neither the Commission nor the
SBA has developed a small business
size standard specifically for operator
service providers. The appropriate size
standard under SBA rules is for the
category Wired Telecommunications
Carriers. Under that size standard, such
a business is small if it has 1,500 or
fewer employees. According to
Commission data, 33 carriers have
reported that they are engaged in the
provision of operator services. Of these,
an estimated 31 have 1,500 or fewer
employees and two have more than
1,500 employees. Consequently, the
Commission estimates that the majority
of OSPs are small entities.
4. Wireless Providers—Fixed and
Mobile
160. Wireless Telecommunications
Carriers (except Satellite). This industry
comprises establishments engaged in
operating and maintaining switching
and transmission facilities to provide
communications via the airwaves.
Establishments in this industry have
spectrum licenses and provide services
using that spectrum, such as cellular
services, paging services, wireless
internet access, and wireless video
services. The appropriate size standard
under SBA rules is that such a business
is small if it has 1,500 or fewer
employees. For this industry, U.S.
Census data for 2012 show that there
were 967 firms that operated for the
PO 00000
Frm 00086
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
entire year. Of this total, 955 firms had
employment of 999 or fewer employees
and 12 had employment of 1000
employees or more. Thus under this
category and the associated size
standard, the Commission estimates that
the majority of wireless
telecommunications carriers (except
satellite) are small entities.
161. The Commission’s own data—
available in its Universal Licensing
System—indicate that, as of October 25,
2016, there are 280 Cellular licensees
that will be affected by our actions
today. The Commission does not know
how many of these licensees are small,
as the Commission does not collect that
information for these types of entities.
Similarly, according to internally
developed Commission data, 413
carriers reported that they were engaged
in the provision of wireless telephony,
including cellular service, Personal
Communications Service, and
Specialized Mobile Radio Telephony
services. Of this total, an estimated 261
have 1,500 or fewer employees, and 152
have more than 1,500 employees. Thus,
using available data, we estimate that
the majority of wireless firms can be
considered small.
162. Wireless Communications
Services. This service can be used for
fixed, mobile, radiolocation, and digital
audio broadcasting satellite uses. The
Commission defined ‘‘small business’’
for the wireless communications
services (WCS) auction as an entity with
average gross revenues of $40 million
for each of the three preceding years,
and a ‘‘very small business’’ as an entity
with average gross revenues of $15
million for each of the three preceding
years. The SBA has approved these
definitions.
163. Wireless Telephony. Wireless
telephony includes cellular, personal
communications services, and
specialized mobile radio telephony
carriers. As noted, the SBA has
developed a small business size
standard for Wireless
Telecommunications Carriers (except
Satellite). Under the SBA small business
size standard, a business is small if it
has 1,500 or fewer employees.
According to Commission data, 413
carriers reported that they were engaged
in wireless telephony. Of these, an
estimated 261 have 1,500 or fewer
employees and 152 have more than
1,500 employees. Therefore, a little less
than one third of these entities can be
considered small.
5. Cable Service Providers
164. Because section 706 requires us
to monitor the deployment of broadband
using any technology, we anticipate that
E:\FR\FM\28DER1.SGM
28DER1
amozie on DSK3GDR082PROD with RULES
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 248 / Friday, December 28, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
some broadband service providers may
not provide telephone service.
Accordingly, we describe below other
types of firms that may provide
broadband services, including cable
companies, MDS providers, and
utilities, among others.
165. Cable and Other Subscription
Programming. This industry comprises
establishments primarily engaged in
operating studios and facilities for the
broadcasting of programs on a
subscription or fee basis. The broadcast
programming is typically narrowcast in
nature (e.g. limited format, such as
news, sports, education, or youthoriented). These establishments produce
programming in their own facilities or
acquire programming from external
sources. The programming material is
usually delivered to a third party, such
as cable systems or direct-to-home
satellite systems, for transmission to
viewers. The SBA has established a size
standard for this industry stating that a
business in this industry is small if it
has 1,500 or fewer employees. The 2012
Economic Census indicates that 367
firms were operational for that entire
year. Of this total, 357 operated with
less than 1,000 employees. Accordingly,
we conclude that a substantial majority
of firms in this industry are small under
the applicable SBA size standard.
166. Cable Companies and Systems
(Rate Regulation). The Commission has
developed its own small business size
standards for the purpose of cable rate
regulation. Under the Commission’s
rules, a ‘‘small cable company’’ is one
serving 400,000 or fewer subscribers
nationwide. Industry data indicate that
there are currently 4,600 active cable
systems in the United States. Of this
total, all but eleven cable operators
nationwide are small under the 400,000subscriber size standard. In addition,
under the Commission’s rate regulation
rules, a ‘‘small system’’ is a cable system
serving 15,000 or fewer subscribers.
Current Commission records show 4,600
cable systems nationwide. Of this total,
3,900 cable systems have fewer than
15,000 subscribers, and 700 systems
have 15,000 or more subscribers, based
on the same records. Thus, under this
standard as well, we estimate that most
cable systems are small entities.
167. Cable System Operators
(Telecom Act Standard). The
Communications Act also contains a
size standard for small cable system
operators, which is ‘‘a cable operator
that, directly or through an affiliate,
serves in the aggregate fewer than 1% of
all subscribers in the United States and
is not affiliated with any entity or
entities whose gross annual revenues in
the aggregate exceed $250,000,000.’’
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:02 Dec 27, 2018
Jkt 247001
There are approximately 52,403,705
cable video subscribers in the United
States today. Accordingly, an operator
serving fewer than 524,037 subscribers
shall be deemed a small operator if its
annual revenues, when combined with
the total annual revenues of all its
affiliates, do not exceed $250 million in
the aggregate. Based on available data,
we find that all but nine incumbent
cable operators are small entities under
this size standard. The Commission
neither requests nor collects information
on whether cable system operators are
affiliated with entities whose gross
annual revenues exceed $250 million.
Although it seems certain that some of
these cable system operators are
affiliated with entities whose gross
annual revenues exceed $250 million,
we are unable at this time to estimate
with greater precision the number of
cable system operators that would
qualify as small cable operators under
the definition in the Communications
Act.
168. All Other Telecommunications.
‘‘All Other Telecommunications’’ is
defined as follows: This U.S. industry is
comprised of establishments that are
primarily engaged in providing
specialized telecommunications
services, such as satellite tracking,
communications telemetry, and radar
station operation. This industry also
includes establishments primarily
engaged in providing satellite terminal
stations and associated facilities
connected with one or more terrestrial
systems and capable of transmitting
telecommunications to, and receiving
telecommunications from, satellite
systems. Establishments providing
internet services or voice over internet
protocol (VoIP) services via clientsupplied telecommunications
connections are also included in this
industry. The SBA has developed a
small business size standard for ‘‘All
Other Telecommunications,’’ which
consists of all such firms with gross
annual receipts of $32.5 million or less.
For this category, census data for 2012
show that there were 1,442 firms that
operated for the entire year. Of these
firms, a total of 1,400 had gross annual
receipts of less than $25 million.
Consequently, we estimate that the
majority of All Other
Telecommunications firms are small
entities that might be affected by our
action.
E. Description of Projected Reporting,
Recordkeeping, and Other Compliance
Requirements for Small Entities
169. Recordkeeping and Reporting.
The rule revisions adopted in the Order
include changes that will require
PO 00000
Frm 00087
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
67119
electing rate-of-return carriers receiving
fixed universal service support to make
various revisions to their business data
service tariffs. For example, rate-ofreturn carriers receiving fixed support
that elect incentive regulation will be
required to file Tariff Review Plans and
incentive regulation tariffs for their
lower capacity TDM BDS. Packet-based
BDS and higher capacity TDM BDS end
user channel termination and lower
capacity TDM BDS end user channel
terminations offered by electing carriers
in study areas deemed competitive by a
competitive market test will be relieved
of ex ante pricing regulation and will be
subject to permissive detariffing for a
period of 36 months at which time they
will be subject to mandatory detariffing.
170. The Commission also
incorporates a productivity factor (Xfactor) of 2.0% and GDP–PI as the
inflation factor used to adjust price cap
indexes in the first year of incentive
regulation, and each year thereafter for
electing carriers. Electing carriers will
be required to revise their rates and
tariff review plans for business data
services in filings with the Commission
to reflect the new X-factor. Finally, the
Commission grants forbearance from the
requirement in § 54.1305 of our rules
annually to report unseparated loop
costs and other accounting data to
NECA.
F. Steps Taken To Minimize the
Significant Economic Impact on Small
Entities and Significant Alternatives
Considered
171. The RFA requires an agency to
describe any significant alternatives that
it has considered in reaching its
proposed approach, which may include
(among others) the following four
alternatives: (1) The establishment of
differing compliance or reporting
requirements or timetables that take into
account the resources available to small
entities; (2) the clarification,
consolidation, or simplification of
compliance or reporting requirements
under the rule for small entities; (3) the
use of performance, rather than design,
standards; and (4) an exemption from
coverage of the rule, or any part thereof,
for small entities.
172. Incentive Regulation. In the
Order, the Commission sheds
burdensome rate-of-return regulation in
favor of lighter touch incentive
regulation for electing carriers’ lower
capacity TDM transport and end user
channel termination services.
Additionally, the Commission adopted
the proposal in the NPRM to grant
pricing flexibility to electing carriers’
lower capacity TDM transport and end
user channel termination services under
E:\FR\FM\28DER1.SGM
28DER1
amozie on DSK3GDR082PROD with RULES
67120
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 248 / Friday, December 28, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
incentive regulation similar to the
pricing flexibility the Commission
granted to price cap carriers’ lower
capacity TDM end user channel
terminations in areas deemed noncompetitive in the BDS Order. The
pricing flexibility available to electing
carriers, most of which are small
entities, will enable them to sell their
BDS using contract tariffs and term and
volume discounts, enhancing their
ability to respond to competition.
173. Competitive Market Test. The
Commission sought comment on four
options for a competitive market test for
electing rate-of-return carriers that
receive fixed support. The option we
selected is one of the least burdensome
options and relies on existing Form 477
data, avoiding any additional
burdensome data collection. We did not
adopt the proposal to use both prongs of
the BDS Order competitive market test
to assess the competitiveness of study
areas served by rate-of-return carriers
that receive fixed support despite its
apparent simplicity because we found
methodological and conceptual flaws in
the proposal and in the study submitted
by Petitioners to support the proposal.
Among the flaws the Commission
identified is that the study does not
claim to be based on a representative
sample of model-based rate-of-return
carriers that receive fixed support, the
study compares non-urbanized price
cap areas with model-based rate-ofreturn areas that in some instances
include urbanized areas, and some of
the relevant counties included in the
study were deemed non-competitive by
the price cap competitive market test.
Further, the Commission declined to
adopt the other two options from the
NPRM which would have required
costly, time consuming, burdensome
data collections. Instead, the Order
found that the record supports adopting
the second option from the NPRM
which uses the second prong of the BDS
Order competitive market test that is
based on Form 477 data. As a result, ex
ante pricing regulation of lower capacity
TDM end user channel terminations
will no longer apply in study areas
served by rate-of-return carriers that
receive fixed support that are deemed
competitive.
174. Packet-based and Higher
Capacity TDM Business Data Services.
The Commission removed ex ante
pricing regulation for electing rate-ofreturn carriers’ packet-based and higher
capacity TDM business data services
and directed electing carriers to detariff
these services following a transition
period. This action is consistent with
the Commission’s preference to
minimize the burdens of regulation.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:02 Dec 27, 2018
Jkt 247001
175. X-factor. Rate-of-return carriers
that receive fixed support that elect
incentive regulation are required to file
revised annual access charge tariffs
every year, which become effective on
July 1. The annual filings include
submission of tariff review plans that
are used to support revisions to the
rates, including revisions that pertain to
the X-factor. To ease the burden on the
industry in connection with this filing,
and because base period demand and
the value of GDP–PI reflected in the
price cap indices typically are not
updated during a tariff year, the
Commission permits electing carriers to
use, in their filings implementing the
2.0% X-factor, the same base period
demand and value of GDP–PI as in the
prior year’s annual filing.
176. Periodic Revision to Competitive
Market Test. Related to the competitive
market test proposal, the Commission
also proposed future periodic data
collections to allow for market test
updates for determining competitive
and non-competitive areas. The periodic
collections could have resulted in a
significant reporting burden on small
entities. Instead, the Commission
adopted a process for updating the
competitive market test every three
years using the data from Form 477 that
is already routinely filed by providers
and thus entails no additional
recordkeeping or reporting burden.
177. Forbearance. The Commission
granted forbearance, pursuant to section
10 of the Act, from the Cost Assignment
Rules for electing carriers, subject to the
requirement relating to the calculation
of pole attachment rates. The
Commission found that the Cost
Assignment Rules are no longer
necessary to ensure that charges and
practices are just, reasonable, and not
unjustly or unreasonably
discriminatory; to protect consumers;
and to protect the public interest. The
Commission found that the rules were
no longer necessary for carriers
converting to incentive regulation and
that eliminating unnecessary regulation
will generally reduce providers’ costs
and provide a more level playing field
because other providers of similar
services are not subject to these
requirements.
178. Detariffing. To minimize
economic impact, the Commission
provides a transition period to provide
electing rate-of-return carriers that
receive fixed support with sufficient
time to detariff their business data
services. The Commission does not
intend its actions to disturb existing
contractual or other long-term
arrangements, which it grandfathered
PO 00000
Frm 00088
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
and which continue to remain in effect
for the length of the contract.
G. Report to Congress
179. The Commission will send a
copy of the Report and Order, including
this FRFA, in a report to be sent to
Congress pursuant to the Congressional
Review Act. In addition, the
Commission will send a copy of the
Report and Order, including this FRFA,
to the Chief Counsel for Advocacy of the
SBA. A copy of the Order and FRFA (or
summaries thereof) will also be
published in the Federal Register.
V. Procedural Matters
180. Paperwork Reduction Act
Analysis. It was determined that the
final rule makes only non-substantive
changes to currently approved
information collections and therefore
does not require separate Paperwork
Reduction Act approval. The rules are
effective 60 days after publication in the
Federal Register. In addition, we note
that pursuant to the Small Business
Paperwork Relief Act of 2002, we
previously sought specific comment on
how the Commission might further
reduce the information collection
burden for small business concerns with
fewer than 25 employees. We describe
impacts that might affect small
businesses, which includes most
businesses with fewer than 25
employees, in the Final Regulatory
Flexibility Analysis in Section IV above.
181. Congressional Review Act. The
Commission will send a copy of this
Report and Order to Congress and the
Government Accountability Office
pursuant to the Congressional Review
Act, see 5 U.S.C. 801(a)(1)(A).
182. Final Regulatory Flexibility
Analysis. As required by the Regulatory
Flexibility Act (RFA), an Initial
Regulatory Flexibility Analysis (IRFA)
was incorporated into the NPRM. The
Commission sought written public
comment on the possible significant
economic impact on small entities
regarding the proposals addressed in the
NPRM, including comments on the
IRFA. Pursuant to the RFA, a Final
Regulatory Flexibility Analysis is set
forth in Section IV above.
183. Contact Person. For further
information about this proceeding,
please contact Justin Faulb, FCC
Wireline Competition Bureau, Pricing
Policy Division, 445 12th Street SW,
Washington, DC 20554, (202) 418–1589,
Justin.Faulb@fcc.gov.
VI. Ordering Clauses
184. Accordingly, it is ordered that,
pursuant to sections 1, 2, 4(i)–(j), 10,
201(b), 202(a), 214, 303(r), 403, of the
E:\FR\FM\28DER1.SGM
28DER1
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 248 / Friday, December 28, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
Communications Act of 1934, as
amended, and section 706 of the
Telecommunications Act of 1996, 47
U.S.C. 151, 152, 154(i)–(j), 160, 201(b),
202(a), 214, 303(r), 403, 1302, this
Report and Order IS ADOPTED and
shall be effective sixty (60) days after
publication in the Federal Register,
except to the extent expressly addressed
below.
185. It is further ordered that parts 1,
32, 51, 61, and 69 of the Commission’s
rules, 47 CFR parts 1, 32, 51, 61, and 69,
are amended as set forth below, and that
such rule amendments shall be effective
sixty (60) days after publication of this
Report and Order in the Federal
Register.
186. It is further ordered that pursuant
to sections 201(b) and 202(a) of the
Communications Act of 1934, as
amended, 47 U.S.C. 201(b), 202(a), rateof-return carriers electing to offer
business data services shall freeze the
tariffed rates for packet-based and
higher capacity TDM services and for
TDM end-user channel terminations at
or below a DS3 in study areas deemed
competitive that the rate-of-return
carrier continues to tariff for six (6)
months following the applicable
effective date of the carrier’s election.
187. It is further ordered that the
Commission’s Consumer &
Governmental Affairs Bureau, Reference
Information Center, shall send a copy of
this Report and Order to Congress and
the Government Accountability Office
pursuant to the Congressional Review
Act, see 5 U.S.C. 801(a)(1)(A).
188. It is further ordered, that the
Commission’s Consumer &
Governmental Affairs Bureau, Reference
Information Center, shall send a copy of
this Report and Order to the Chief
Counsel for Advocacy of the Small
Business Administration.
Federal Communications Commission
Marlene Dortch,
Secretary.
RULES
The Federal Communications
Commission amends 47 CFR parts 1, 32,
51, 61, and 69 as follows:
PART 1—PRACTICE AND
PROCEDURE
1. The authority citation for part 1
continues to read as follows:
■
Authority: 47 U.S.C. 151, 154(i) and (j),
155, 157, 160, 201, 224, 225, 227, 303, 309,
310, 332, 1403, 1404, 1451, 1452, and 1455.
2. Section 1.1406 is amended by
adding paragraph (e) to read as follows:
■
§ 1.1406 Commission consideration of the
complaint.
47 CFR Part 1
Communications common carriers,
Reporting and recordkeeping,
Telecommunications.
PART 32—UNIFORM SYSTEM OF
ACCOUNTS FOR
TELECOMMUNICATIONS COMPANIES
■
47 CFR Part 32
■
*
Communications, Reporting and
recordkeeping requirements, Telephone,
Uniform System of Accounts.
3. The authority citation for part 32
continues to read as follows:
Authority: 47 U.S.C. 219, 220 as amended,
unless otherwise noted.
47 CFR Part 51
■
Communications common carriers,
Telecommunications.
§ 32.1
47 CFR Part 61
Communications common carriers,
Radio, Reporting and recordkeeping
requirements, Telegraph, Telephone.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:02 Dec 27, 2018
Jkt 247001
*
enables both management and
regulators to assess these results within
a specified accounting period. The
USOA also provides the financial
community and others with financial
performance results. In order for an
accounting system to fulfill these
purposes, it must exhibit consistency
and stability in financial reporting
(including the results published for
regulatory purposes). Accordingly, the
USOA has been designed to reflect
stable, recurring financial data based to
the extent regulatory considerations
permit upon the consistency of the wellestablished body of accounting theories
and principles commonly referred to as
generally accepted accounting
principles (GAAP). The rules of this
part, and any other rules or orders that
are derivative of or dependent on the
rules in this part, do not apply to price
cap companies, and rate-of-return
telephone companies offering business
data services pursuant to § 61.50 of this
chapter, that have opted-out of USOA
requirements pursuant to the conditions
specified by the Commission in
§ 32.11(g).
■ 5. Section 32.11 is amended by
revising paragraph (g) to read as follows:
*
*
*
*
(e) A price cap company, or a rate-ofreturn carrier electing to provide service
pursuant to § 61.50 of this chapter, that
opts-out of part 32 of this chapter may
calculate attachment rates for its poles,
ducts, conduits, and rights of way using
either part 32 accounting data or GAAP
accounting data. A company using
GAAP accounting data to compute rates
to attach to its poles, ducts, conduits,
and rights of way in any of the first
twelve years after opting-out must
adjust (increase or decrease) its annually
computed GAAP-based rates by an
Implementation Rate Difference for each
of the remaining years in the period.
The Implementation Rate Difference
means the difference between
attachment rates calculated by the
carrier under part 32 and under GAAP
as of the last full year preceding the
carrier’s initial opting-out of part 32
USOA accounting requirements.
List of Subjects
amozie on DSK3GDR082PROD with RULES
47 CFR Part 69
Communications common carriers,
Reporting and recordkeeping
requirements, Telephone.
4. Section 32.1 is revised to read as
follows:
Background.
The revised Uniform System of
Accounts (USOA) is a historical
financial accounting system which
reports the results of operational and
financial events in a manner which
PO 00000
Frm 00089
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
67121
§ 32.11
Companies subject to this part.
*
*
*
*
*
(g) Notwithstanding paragraph (a) of
this section, a price cap company, or a
rate-of-return telephone company
offering business data services pursuant
to § 61.50 of this chapter, that elects to
calculate its pole attachment rates
pursuant to § 1.1406(e) of this chapter
will not be subject to this Uniform
System of Accounts.
PART 51—INTERCONNECTION
6. The authority citation for part 51
continues to read as follows:
■
Authority: 47 U.S.C. 151–55, 201–05, 207–
09, 218, 225–27, 251–52, 271, 332 unless
otherwise noted.
7. Section 51.903 is amended by
revising paragraph (g) to read as follows:
§ 51.903
Definitions.
*
*
*
*
(g) Rate-of-Return Carrier is any
incumbent local exchange carrier not
subject to price cap regulation as that
term is defined in § 61.3(bb) of this
chapter, but only with respect to the
territory in which it operates as an
incumbent local exchange carrier.
*
*
*
*
*
PART 61—TARIFFS
8. The authority citation for part 61
continues to read as follows:
■
E:\FR\FM\28DER1.SGM
28DER1
67122
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 248 / Friday, December 28, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
Authority: 47 U.S.C. 151, 154(i), 154(j),
201–05 and 403, unless otherwise noted.
9. Section 61.41 is amended by
revising paragraph (d) and adding
paragraph (f) to read as follows:
■
§ 61.41
Price cap requirements generally.
*
*
*
*
*
(d) Except as provided in paragraph
(e) of this section, local exchange
carriers that become subject to price cap
regulation as that term is defined in
§ 61.3(ff) shall not be eligible to
withdraw from such regulation.
*
*
*
*
*
(f) Notwithstanding the requirements
of paragraphs (c) and (d) of this section,
a telephone company subject to rate-ofreturn regulation that is affiliated with
a price cap local exchange carrier may
provide business data services pursuant
to § 61.50 without converting other
services to price cap regulation.
■ 10. Section 61.50 is added to read as
follows:
amozie on DSK3GDR082PROD with RULES
§ 61.50 Regulation of business data
services offered by rate-of-return carriers
electing incentive regulation.
(a) A rate-of-return carrier, as defined
in § 51.903(g) of this chapter, may elect
to offer its business data services subject
to incentive regulation pursuant to this
section. A rate-of-return carrier may
elect to offer business data services
subject to incentive regulation pursuant
to this section only if all affiliated rateof-return carriers meeting the
requirements of paragraph (b) of this
section make the election. A carrier’s
election under this section is
irrevocable.
(b) A rate-of-return carrier is eligible
to elect incentive regulation for its
business data services if the carrier:
(1) Receives universal service
payments pursuant to the AlternativeConnect America Cost Model pursuant
to § 54.311 of this chapter;
(2) Is an affiliate of a price cap local
exchange carrier operating pursuant to a
waiver of § 61.41;
(3) Receives universal service
payments pursuant to § 54.306 of this
chapter; or
(4) Transitions away from legacy
support mechanisms in the future.
(c) A rate-of-return carrier electing to
offer business data services pursuant to
this section shall employ the procedures
outlined in §§ 61.42 through 61.49 to
calculate rates for its business data
services and adjust its indexes for those
rates to the extent those sections are
applicable to business data services,
except that:
(1) Exogenous costs associated with
regulated services shall be allocated to
business data services based on relative
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:02 Dec 27, 2018
Jkt 247001
regulated business data services
revenues, compared to regulated
revenues and related support receipts;
and
(2) An electing carrier is not required
to file a short form tariff review plan as
required by § 61.49(k).
(d) A rate-of-return carrier electing to
offer business data services pursuant to
this section must remove its business
data services from the NECA Traffic
Sensitive Pool. Such a carrier may
continue to participate in the NECA
Traffic Sensitive Pool and tariff for
access services other than business data
services.
(e) A rate-of-return carrier offering
business data services pursuant to this
section may offer those business data
services at different rates in different
study areas.
(f) A rate-of-return carrier offering
business data services pursuant to this
section may make a low-end adjustment
pursuant to § 61.45(d)(1)(vii) unless it:
(1) Exercises the regulatory relief
pursuant to paragraph (g) of this section
in any part of its service region; or
(2) Exercises the option to use
Generally Accepted Accounting
Principles rather than the part 32
Uniform System of Accounts pursuant
to § 32.11(g) of this chapter.
(g) A rate-of-return carrier electing to
offer business data services pursuant to
this section may offer time division
multiplexed transport and end user
channel termination services at or below
a DS3 bandwidth that include:
(1) Volume and term discounts;
(2) Contract-based tariffs, provided
that:
(i) Contract-based tariff services are
made generally available to all similarly
situated customers; and
(ii) The rate-of-return carrier excludes
all contract-based tariff offerings from
incentive regulation; and
(3) The ability to file tariff revisions
on at least one day’s notice,
notwithstanding the notice
requirements for tariff filings specified
in § 61.58.
(h) A rate-of-return carrier electing to
offer business data services pursuant to
this section shall comply with the
requirements of § 69.805 of this chapter
in its study areas deemed noncompetitive pursuant to this section.
(i) The regulation of other services
offered by a carrier that offers business
data services pursuant to this section
shall not be modified as a result of the
requirements of this section.
(j)(1) The Wireline Competition
Bureau will conduct an initial
competitive market test for rate-ofreturn carriers eligible to elect incentive
regulation pursuant to this section.
PO 00000
Frm 00090
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
Study areas of such carriers will be
deemed competitive if 75 percent of the
census blocks within the study area are
reported to have a minimum of 10 Mbps
download and 1 Mbps upload
broadband service offered by a cable
operator based on the most current
publicly available Form 477 data. A list
of study areas deemed competitive by
the competitive market test will be
published on the Commission’s website.
(2) The Wireline Competition Bureau
will conduct subsequent competitive
market tests for rate-of-return carriers
electing incentive regulation pursuant to
this section contemporaneously with
the subsequent tests mandated by
§ 69.803 of this chapter for price cap
carriers.
(3) A study area of an electing carrier
deemed competitive by the competitive
market test will retain its status in
subsequent tests.
(k)(1) Packet-based and time division
multiplexed business data services
above a DS3 bandwidth offered by a
rate-of-return carrier pursuant to this
section shall not be subject to ex ante
pricing regulation.
(2) Time division multiplexed end
user channel termination business data
services at or below a DS3 bandwidth
offered by a rate-of-return carrier
pursuant to this section in study areas
deemed competitive by the competitive
market test shall not be subject to ex
ante pricing regulation.
(3) A rate-of-return carrier electing
incentive regulation for its business data
services must detariff:
(i) All packet-based and time division
multiplexed business data services
above a DS3 bandwidth within thirtysix months after the effective date of its
election of incentive regulation; and
(ii) All time division multiplexed end
user channel termination business data
services at or below a DS3 bandwidth in
any study area deemed competitive by
the competitive market test within
thirty-six months after such services
shall be deemed competitive in a study
area.
(l)(1) A rate-of-return carrier electing
incentive regulation for its business data
services effective July 1, 2019 must
notify the Chief of the Wireline
Competition Bureau of its election by
May 1, 2019 for it to become effective
concurrent with the annual access tariff
filing in 2019.
(2) A rate-of-return carrier electing
incentive regulation for its business data
services effective July 1, 2020 must
notify the Chief of the Wireline
Competition Bureau of its election by
May 1, 2020 for it to become effective
concurrent with the annual access tariff
filing in 2020.
E:\FR\FM\28DER1.SGM
28DER1
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 248 / Friday, December 28, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
(3) A rate-of-return carrier accepting
future offers of Alternative-Connect
America Cost Model support or
otherwise transitioning away from
legacy support mechanisms and electing
incentive regulation for its business data
services must notify the Chief of the
Wireline Competition Bureau of its
election by May 1 following its
acceptance of the offer for it to become
effective concurrent with that year’s
annual access tariff filing.
■ 11. Section 61.55 is amended by
revising paragraph (a) to read as follows:
§ 61.55
Contract-based tariffs.
(a) This section shall apply to price
cap local exchange carriers permitted to
offer contract-based tariffs under § 1.776
or § 69.805 of this chapter, as well as to
the offering of business data services by
rate-of-return carriers pursuant to
§ 61.50.
*
*
*
*
*
PART 69—ACCESS CHARGES
12. The authority citation for part 69
continues to read as follows:
■
Authority: 47 U.S.C. 154, 201, 202, 203,
205, 218, 220, 254, 403.
13. Section 69.114 is amended by
revising paragraph (a) to read as follows:
■
§ 69.114
Special access.
(a) Appropriate subelements shall be
established for the use of equipment or
facilities that are assigned to the Special
Access element for purposes of
apportioning net investment, or that are
equivalent to such equipment or
facilities for companies subject to price
cap regulation as that term is defined in
§ 61.3(ff) of this chapter.
*
*
*
*
*
[FR Doc. 2018–27528 Filed 12–27–18; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6712–01–P
DEPARTMENT OF HOMELAND
SECURITY
48 CFR Parts 3019 and 3052
[Docket No. DHS–2018–0024]
amozie on DSK3GDR082PROD with RULES
RIN 1601–AA83
Rescinding Department of Homeland
Security Acquisition Regulation
(HSAR) Clause Regarding Small
Business Subcontracting Plan
Reporting (HSAR Case 2017–001)
Office of the Chief Procurement
Officer, Department of Homeland
Security (DHS).
ACTION: Final rule.
AGENCY:
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:07 Dec 27, 2018
Jkt 247001
This final rule amends the
HSAR by removing the HSAR clause
regarding small business subcontracting
plan reporting because the requirements
of this clause duplicate the
requirements in a Federal Acquisition
Regulation (FAR) clause. The HSAR
clause is no longer needed to provide
guidance to contractors and DHS
proposes to remove the clause from the
HSAR.
DATES: Effective Date: January 28, 2019.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: Ms.
Candace Lightfoot, Procurement
Analyst, DHS, Office of the Chief
Procurement Officer, Acquisition Policy
and Legislation at (202) 447–0882 or
email HSAR@hq.dhs.gov for
clarification of content. When using
email, include HSAR Case 2017–001 in
the ‘‘Subject’’ line.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION:
SUMMARY:
I. Background
In a Notice of Proposed Rulemaking
(NPRM) published in the Federal
Register (83 FR 25638) on June 4, 2018,
the Department of Homeland Security,
Office of the Chief Procurement Officer,
proposed to remove HSAR clause
3052.219–70 and the cross-reference to
it found in paragraph (a) of 48 CFR
3019.708–70.
As explained in the NPRM, on
December 4, 2003, DHS published an
interim final rule to establish the
Department of Homeland Security
Acquisition Regulation (HSAR). 68 FR
67867 (Dec. 4, 2003). On May 2, 2006,
DHS published a final rule, which
adopted the interim rule with some
changes in response to public comment
(HSAR final rule). 71 FR 25759 (May 2,
2006). The HSAR final rule finalized,
among other things, HSAR clause
3052.219–70, Small Business
Subcontracting Reporting Plan (48 CFR
3052.219–70). HSAR clause 3052.219–
70 requires contractors to: (a) Enter the
information for the Subcontracting
Report for Individual Contracts
(formally the Standard Form 294 (SF–
294)) and the Summary Subcontract
Report (formally the Standard Form 295
(SF–295)) into the Electronic
Subcontracting Reporting System (eSRS)
at www.esrs.gov; and (b) include HSAR
clause 3052.219.70 in all subcontracts
that include the clause at (FAR) 48 CFR
52.219–9. The eSRS is a web-based
system, which replaces the Standard
Forms 294 and 295 as the mechanism
for submitting reports required by the
small business subcontracting program.
On June 16, 2010, the Civilian Agency
Acquisition Council and the Defense
Acquisition Regulations Council issued
a final rule amending the Federal
PO 00000
Frm 00091
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
67123
Acquisition Regulation (FAR) to require
contractors’ small business subcontract
reports be submitted using the eSRS,
rather than Standard Forms 294 and
295. 75 FR 34260; FAR Case 2005–040
(June 16, 2010). This change to the FAR
was issued under Federal Acquisition
Circular 2005–42 of June 16, 2010. 75
FR 34291 (June 16, 2010). As a result of
the FAR revision HSAR clause
3052.219–70 is no longer needed to
provide guidance to contractors on the
eSRS requirements. Therefore, DHS is
amending the HSAR to remove HSAR
clause 3052.219–70 and the crossreference to it found in paragraph (a) of
48 CFR 3019.708–70.
In addition, DHS is also to amending
the authority citation for part 3019 to
conform with the authority of the
Positive Law Codification of Title 41,
United States code, ‘‘Public Contracts’’.
The new codification of Title 41 was
enacted on January 4, 2011.1
II. Discussion and Analysis
Interested parties were given until
July 5, 2018, to comment on the
proposed changes. No public comments
were submitted in response to the
proposed rule. Accordingly, DHS will
adopt the proposal as set forth in the
NPRM without change.
III. Executive Orders 12866, 13563, and
13771
Executive Orders 13563 (‘‘Improving
Regulation and Regulatory Review’’)
and 12866 (‘‘Regulatory Planning and
Review’’) direct agencies to assess the
costs and benefits of available regulatory
alternatives and, if regulation is
necessary, to select regulatory
approaches that maximize net benefits
(including potential economic,
environmental, public health and safety
effects, distributive impacts, and
equity). Executive Order 13563
emphasizes the importance of
quantifying both costs and benefits, of
reducing costs, of harmonizing rules,
and of promoting flexibility. Executive
Order 13771 (‘‘Reducing Regulation and
Controlling Regulatory Costs’’) directs
agencies to reduce regulation and
control regulatory costs and provides
that ‘‘for every one new regulation
issued, at least two prior regulations be
identified for elimination, and that the
cost of planned regulations be prudently
managed and controlled through a
budgeting process.’’
The Office of Management and Budget
(OMB) has not designated this rule a
‘‘significant regulatory action,’’ under
section 3(f) of Executive Order 12866.
Accordingly, OMB has not reviewed it.
1 See
E:\FR\FM\28DER1.SGM
Public Law 111–350, (Jan. 4, 2011).
28DER1
Agencies
[Federal Register Volume 83, Number 248 (Friday, December 28, 2018)]
[Rules and Regulations]
[Pages 67098-67123]
From the Federal Register Online via the Government Publishing Office [www.gpo.gov]
[FR Doc No: 2018-27528]
=======================================================================
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION
47 CFR Parts 1, 32, 51, 61, and 69
[WC Docket Nos. 17-144, 16-143, 05-25; FCC 18-146]
Regulation of Business Data Services for Rate-of-Return Local
Exchange Carriers; Business Data Services in an internet Protocol
Environment; Special Access for Price Cap Local Exchange Carriers
AGENCY: Federal Communications Commission.
ACTION: Final rule.
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
SUMMARY: The Commission continues its efforts to modernize its rules
governing the pricing of business data services (BDS) by allowing rate-
of-return carriers to voluntarily elect to transition their BDS
offerings out of rate-of-return regulation to a lighter-touch
regulatory framework. This action is intended to promote competition
and reduce costly regulatory burdens which no longer serve the public
interest. Under this new framework, rate-of-return carriers would be
incentivized to use the savings realized from the regulatory relief to
improve existing networks and service.
DATES: The amendments contained in this final rule shall become
effective February 26, 2019.
ADDRESSES: Federal Communications Commission, 445 12th Street SW,
Washington, DC 20554.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: Justin Faulb, Pricing Policy Division
of the Wireline Competition Bureau at 202-418-1540 or by email at
Justin.Faulb@fcc.gov.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: This is a summary of the Commission's Report
and Order, released October 24, 2018. A full-text version may be
obtained at the following internet address: https://www.fcc.gov/document/fcc-spurs-competition-rural-business-data-services-0.
I. Background
1. In 1990, the Commission began the process of encouraging
carriers to move from rate-of-return to incentive regulation by
adopting price cap rules governing the largest incumbent LECs'
interstate access charges and allowing other incumbent LECs to elect
price cap regulation voluntarily. Price cap regulation was designed to
``reward companies that became more productive and efficient, while
ensuring that productivity and efficiency gains are shared with
ratepayers.'' Through a series of subsequent decisions, the Commission
allowed other carriers to convert voluntarily from rate-of-return to
price cap regulation.
2. Since then, the Commission has taken additional steps to
transition certain services and revenues of rate-of-return carriers
from rate-of-return regulation to other more efficient forms of
regulation. In 2011, as part of comprehensive universal service and
intercarrier compensation reform, the Commission imposed rate caps on
rate-of-return carriers' switched access services, removing those
services from the obligations that accompany traditional rate-or-return
regulation. In the USF/ICC Transformation Order, 76 FR 73830, November
29, 2011, the Commission also changed its method for calculating high-
cost universal service support received by rate-of-return affiliates of
price cap carriers. Specifically, the Commission began to treat rate-
of-return operating companies affiliated with price-cap holding
companies as price cap LECs for the purposes of the Connect America
Fund (CAF) Phase I distribution mechanism. As a result, rate-of-return
carriers affiliated with price-cap companies now receive the same type
of fixed universal service support that their price cap affiliates
receive.
3. Two years ago, the Commission gave rate-of-return carriers the
option of receiving forward looking, model-based universal service
support based on the Alternative Connect America Cost Model (A-CAM),
which more than 200 carriers opted to receive (A-CAM carriers). The
Commission observed that ``the carriers that choose to take the
voluntary path to the model are electing incentive regulation for
common line offerings.'' Consequently, for A-CAM carriers, only their
BDS offerings are currently subject to rate-of-return regulation.
4. In 2016, the Commission also adopted the Alaska Plan Order, 81
FR 69696, October 7, 2016, which allowed Alaskan rate-of-return
carriers to elect fixed universal service support on a state-wide basis
for a defined term in exchange for committing to deployment
obligations. Specifically, the Commission provided a one-time
opportunity for Alaskan rate-of-return carriers to elect to receive
universal service support frozen at adjusted 2011 levels for a 10-year
term in exchange for meeting individualized performance benchmarks to
offer voice and broadband services. Subsequently, in 2016, the Wireline
Competition Bureau (Bureau) authorized 13 Alaskan rate-of-return
carriers to receive universal service support under the Alaska Plan
(Alaska Plan carriers). Similar to A-CAM carriers, Alaska Plan carriers
receive fixed universal service support that is not based on current
cost, and only file cost studies for purposes of their BDS offerings.
5. In addition to encouraging carriers to migrate from cost-based
to incentive regulation, over time the Commission has reduced ex ante
pricing regulation in favor of relying on competition to the extent
possible. In 1999, the Commission granted pricing flexibility to price
cap carriers that provided service in areas where carriers could
demonstrate threshold levels of deployment by competitive providers.
Pricing flexibility allowed eligible carriers to offer BDS using
contract tariffs, volume and term discounts and, in markets that
demonstrated higher levels of competition, at unregulated rates.
Beginning in 2007, the Commission granted forbearance from dominant
carrier regulation, including tariffing and pricing regulation, to a
number of price cap incumbent LECs for their newer packet-based
broadband services. These forbearance orders concluded that forbearance
from dominant carrier regulation was warranted given the existence of
competition for these newer services, which ensured that rates and
practices for these services remained just and reasonable, adequately
protected consumers, and was in the public interest.
6. In 2017, the Commission adjusted BDS pricing regulation to the
reality of a dynamically competitive BDS market in areas where
incumbent LECs were subject to price cap regulation. The Commission
premised its reductions in ex ante pricing regulation in part on a
substantial data collection and in part on its predictive judgment that
dynamic and growing competition in the BDS market, driven increasingly
by the emergence of cable competition, would allow reliance on
competition rather than regulation to ensure rates remain just and
reasonable. The BDS Order, 82 FR 25660, June 2, 2017, represented yet
another step in the process of reducing dominant carrier regulation in
response to the growth of competition. In that order, the Commission
found that reducing government intervention and allowing market forces
to continue working would further spur entry, innovation, and
competition in BDS markets served by price cap carriers.
[[Page 67099]]
The Commission applied ex ante pricing regulation ``only where
competition is expected to materially fail to ensure just and
reasonable rates'' and stated its preference to rely ``on competition
rather than regulation, wherever purchasers can realistically turn to a
supplier beyond the incumbent LEC.'' Based on the record before it, the
Commission found that, on balance, competition was sufficient to ensure
just and reasonable rates for packet-based business data services, TDM
transport services, and higher bandwidth (i.e., above a DS3-level) TDM
services (including OCn services) in the absence of ex ante pricing
regulation in areas served by price cap carriers. It also adopted a
competitive market test for lower bandwidth TDM end user channel
terminations (i.e., DS3-level and lower) in price cap areas and
refrained from ex ante pricing regulation of those services in areas
deemed competitive by that test.
7. Recently, the Eighth Circuit Court of Appeals upheld all aspects
of the BDS Order save the portions of the order affecting price cap
carriers' TDM transport service, which it vacated and remanded on
notice grounds--namely that the Commission had not provided sufficient
notice that it might relieve those services of ex ante pricing
regulation.
8. After the Commission adopted changes to its rules governing
price cap carriers' BDS offerings, ITTA and USTelecom (together,
Petitioners) filed a petition seeking the same regulatory treatment of
BDS offerings for rate-of-return carriers receiving fixed support as
that the Commission had recently adopted for price cap carriers (Joint
Petition). According to Petitioners, rate-of-return regulation deters
investment in networks and harms competition. Petitioners argue that
the inflexibility of rate-of-return regulation makes it difficult to
justify and fund upgrades to their rural networks. They point out that
for rate-of-return carriers, ``the need to perform annual cost studies
now applies only with respect to BDS.'' As a result, they argue that
the expense associated with conducting cost studies and complying with
other rate-of-return expenses are difficult to recover and burden rate-
of-return carriers receiving fixed support but not their competitors.
The Bureau sought and received comment on the Joint Petition.
9. Upon review of the record received in response to the Joint
Petition, earlier this year, the Commission released a notice of
proposed rulemaking (NPRM), 83 FR 22923, May 17, 2018, proposing to
allow A-CAM and other rate-of-return carriers that receive fixed
universal service support to voluntarily migrate their lower speed TDM-
based BDS offerings to incentive regulation. The Commission also sought
comment on adopting a competitive market test to determine when the
market for lower speed TDM-based BDS offerings offered by rate-of-
return carriers that receive fixed support are sufficiently competitive
to justify eliminating ex ante pricing regulation of such offerings.
Additionally, the NPRM sought comment on eliminating ex ante pricing
regulation for such carriers' packet-based and higher speed TDM-based
BDS offerings nationwide, while maintaining oversight authority through
sections 201, 202, and 208 of the Communications Act of 1934, as
amended (the Communications Act or the Act) to ensure BDS rates and
practices remain just and reasonable.
II. An Administrable Framework for Business Data Services Offered By
Rate-of-Return Carriers That Receive Fixed Support
10. Upon review of the record, we allow rate-of-return carriers
receiving fixed universal service support to choose to migrate their
BDS offerings to a new, comprehensive, lighter-touch regulatory
framework that is better aligned to the competitive realities of the
BDS markets they serve. The framework we adopt includes voluntary
incentive regulation with pricing flexibility for electing carriers'
lower capacity (DS3 and below) TDM transport and end user channel
termination services. We also adopt a competitive market test for such
carriers' lower capacity TDM end user channel termination services to
identify competition by study area. In electing carriers' study areas
that the competitive market test deems competitive, we eliminate ex
ante pricing regulation for lower capacity TDM end user channel
termination services. We also remove ex ante pricing regulation from
electing carriers' packet-based and higher capacity (above a DS3
bandwidth level) TDM services and grant forbearance from tariffing
requirements for those services. To reduce the burden of legacy rate-
of-return regulation on electing carriers, we also grant forbearance
from cost assignment and separations rules and related reporting
requirements, because we determine that such action is warranted by the
non-cost-based regulation that will apply to electing carriers and the
competitive circumstances of their BDS markets.
11. We find that adopting the lighter-touch incentive regulatory
framework proposed by the Commission for electing carriers will remove
unnecessary regulatory burdens and encourage competition. Based on the
record before us, we decline at this time to relieve electing carriers'
lower capacity TDM transport (at or below a DS3-level) of ex ante
pricing regulation nationwide, as Petitioners sought. Instead we allow
electing carriers to move their lower speed TDM transport services to
incentive regulation. Additionally, we adopt a competitive market test
tailored to rate-of-return carriers' study areas, which will allow us
to properly evaluate competition in the areas served by electing
carriers and remove ex ante pricing regulation for end user channel
terminations in areas deemed competitive, instead of basing our
decision on the competitive characteristics of areas served by price
cap carriers.
12. We decline to adopt Petitioners' proposal to apply to electing
carriers' BDS offerings the regulatory framework and the results of the
price cap competitive market test adopted in the BDS Order for price
cap carriers' BDS offerings. Petitioners argue that applying the price
cap BDS rules to electing rate-of-return carriers would result in
regulatory parity that ``would promote competition and make the rules
less complex.'' TDS Telecom asserts that adopting a separate incentive
regulatory framework is unnecessary. The price cap BDS rules, however,
were based on an analysis of BDS competition in areas served by price
cap carriers, consistent with our obligation to ensure that the rates
charged by common carriers are just and reasonable. The Commission
found sufficient evidence of competition in these areas to discipline
pricing and therefore adopt a lighter touch regulatory framework for
these carriers. That same history and record of competition for BDS
services does not exist in the study areas served by rate-of-return
carriers that Petitioners seek to have covered by price cap BDS
regulation. Thus, we find that adopting a separate, albeit largely
parallel, regulatory framework for rate-of-return carriers receiving
fixed support will be better suited to their circumstances.
A. Transitioning to a New Framework
13. Consistent with the Commission's proposal and the Joint
Petition, we allow all rate-of-return carriers receiving fixed
universal service support to voluntarily elect to move their BDS
offerings out of rate-of-return regulation to the new lighter touch
framework we adopt today. Carriers eligible to make this election
include A-CAM carriers, rate-of-return carriers receiving fixed support
by virtue of being affiliated with price cap carriers, Alaska Plan
carriers,
[[Page 67100]]
and rate-of-return carriers that accept future offers of A-CAM support
or otherwise transition away from legacy support mechanisms. The first
three types of carriers receive fixed or model-based universal service
support, rather than receiving high-cost support based on their costs,
and therefore are currently required to prepare cost studies only for
their BDS offerings. Relieving these carriers of rate-of-return
regulation for their BDS will save them the expense of preparing
burdensome cost studies only for those offerings.
14. Similarly, to the extent the Commission provides future offers
of A-CAM support or otherwise transitions carriers away from legacy
support mechanisms, carriers that receive such support will only have
to prepare cost studies for purposes of their BDS offerings. Therefore,
if the Commission announces future offers of A-CAM support or otherwise
transitions carriers away from legacy support mechanisms, the actions
we take in this Order will allow carriers eligible for or subject to
such transitions to elect the same lighter touch regulatory framework
we provide for other rate-of-return carriers that receive fixed
support, and may provide further incentives for rate-of-return carriers
to elect to receive non-legacy, fixed or model-based support. This will
further the Commission's longstanding objective of providing universal
service support based on forward-looking efficient costs as opposed to
actual costs that may be less efficient.
15. Consistent with Commission precedent, we do not require all
rate-of-return carriers receiving fixed support to migrate their BDS
offerings away from rate-of-return regulation to the new framework, but
instead allow each carrier to voluntarily make that determination based
on its circumstances. When the Commission adopted price cap regulation
in 1990, it made price cap regulation voluntary for all but the largest
incumbent LECs. At that time, the Commission expressed concern that
assigning one productivity factor on a mandatory basis to all LECs,
regardless of size, could prove unduly burdensome for smaller and mid-
sized carriers that may have fewer opportunities than larger companies
to achieve cost savings and efficiencies. Commenters echoed those
concerns in this proceeding. By making the election voluntary, we
ensure that only carriers that can achieve sufficient efficiencies are
likely to elect incentive regulation; our new framework will not,
therefore, impose additional burdens on smaller carriers that cannot
achieve such efficiencies.
16. We also adopt the Commission's proposal to require electing
carriers to elect incentive regulation at the holding company-level for
study areas in all states where that carrier receives fixed support.
Commenters do not oppose requiring holding company-level election. AT&T
requests that the Commission ``require that any A-CAM carrier that
elects incentive regulation have that election apply across all its
study areas'' because this prevents ``internal cost shifting among
study areas.'' Holding company-level election will maximize the
regulatory efficiencies achieved by incentive regulation, including
maximizing cost savings from the elimination of cost studies for all
electing carriers. It is also consistent with the Commission's past
practices. For example, the Commission gave rate-of-return carriers the
opportunity to elect between A-CAM and legacy cost-based support at a
state-wide level. Likewise, the Commission required Alaska Plan
carriers to elect fixed, frozen support on a state-wide basis.
Requiring rate-of-return carriers receiving fixed support to elect
regulatory treatment at the holding company-level is also consistent
with the underlying premise of price cap regulation, which assumed a
broad representation of carrier operations to provide a basis for
establishing an industry-wide productivity factor.
17. We provide eligible carriers with two opportunities to elect to
move their BDS offerings out of rate-of-return regulation--one to be
effective as of July 1, 2019 and a second effective as of July 1,
2020--to encourage them to take advantage without undue delay of the
benefits that will be realized by electing carriers under the new
framework and to discourage potential gaming opportunities. We provide
two opportunities to elect this new regulatory framework, in
recognition of the fact that some carriers may not have sufficient time
to assess their options in time for the July 1, 2019 effective date.
Providing a second opportunity to elect incentive regulation will
facilitate carriers' ability to assess incentive regulation for their
BDS and ultimately enhance participation in the new regulatory
framework, which will further reduce unnecessary regulatory burdens and
positively impact competition in electing carriers' BDS markets.
18. Some commenters recommend that we provide an ``annual
opportunity to elect the new regime'' based on ``business strategy and
compliance measures.'' Giving eligible carriers an annual opportunity
to elect incentive regulation, however, would also give them an
incentive to increase their operating costs and rate base under rate-
of-return regulation in order to raise rates prior to electing
incentive regulation, then realize additional profits by cutting costs
under incentive regulation at the expense of ratepayers. By providing
only two opportunities to elect to move to the new framework, we
discourage such gaming opportunities.
19. We prohibit electing carriers from returning their study areas
to rate-of-return regulation. One of the rationales for the
Commission's ``all-or-nothing'' rules for price cap carriers is to
prevent carriers from potentially switching back and forth between
rate-of-return and price cap regulation to take advantage of uneven
cycles of investment. We are likewise concerned with potential gaming
opportunities for electing carriers if they are allowed to switch back
and forth between rate-of-return and incentive regulation. Electing
carriers could inflate their revenues by opting-out of incentive
regulation, building a larger rate base under rate-of-return regulation
in order to raise rates, and then, returning to incentive regulation or
opting into price cap regulation, thus reducing costs back to an
efficient level. These gaming opportunities would distort carriers'
decisions to invest and frustrate the public interest because
ratepayers would not see the benefit of capped and decreased rates in
the manner intended under incentive regulation. Further, in the 1990
Price Cap Order, 55 FR 42375, October 19, 1990, the Commission
determined that for price cap regulation to work effectively and for
incentives to develop and influence carrier behavior and earnings, an
electing carrier must make a permanent commitment. We similarly find,
that for incentive regulation to work properly, the election must be
permanent. Accordingly, a carrier's voluntary election of incentive
regulation will be irrevocable.
20. AT&T requests that the ``Commission decline to waive the `all-
or-nothing' rule for these carriers and require that any A-CAM carrier
that elects incentive regulation have that election apply across all
its study areas and, even more critically, across all of its interstate
services within a study area.'' The all-or-nothing rule AT&T cites,
however, applies to price cap carriers, not to rate-of-return carriers
that elect incentive regulation. While the incentive regulation rules
we adopt for electing carriers impose price caps on some of the BDS
services offered by electing carriers, electing carriers do not become
price cap carriers by virtue of their election; therefore the all-or-
[[Page 67101]]
nothing rule is simply not applicable here.
21. We allow electing carriers' switched access services to remain
subject to the multi-year transition provided for rate-of-return
carriers in the USF/ICC Transformation Order. We therefore decline to
adopt AT&T's recommendation that electing carriers be required to
convert all their services to price cap regulation, including their
switched access services, which--compared to price-cap carriers'
switched access services--benefit from a longer transition to bill-and-
keep and no phase-out of Connect America Fund Intercarrier Compensation
replacement support.
22. According to AT&T ``[w]hile different transitions for price cap
carriers and rate-of-return carriers may have made sense in 2011, those
distinctions should not unfairly benefit carriers'' electing incentive
regulation and could lead to cost-shifting between types of services.
We disagree with AT&T's assertion that electing carriers will
``unfairly benefit'' from our decision not to convert all of their
offerings to incentive regulation. The Commission adopted different
intercarrier compensation transitions in the context of a complex
rulemaking that were the result of a careful analysis of a variety of
factors and policy considerations, including the differential impact of
universal service and intercarrier compensation reform on price cap as
compared to rate-of-return carriers. As TDS Telecom explains, in the
intervening seven years, carriers have relied on those transitions to
plan their businesses and make investments. Changing those transitions
at this point would disrupt these settled expectations and potentially
undermine, rather than encourage, investment and innovation in electing
carriers' BDS markets. We also find AT&T's concerns about cost-shifting
unfounded because switched access rates were capped and therefore
removed from cost-based regulation in 2011 by the USF/ICC
Transformation Order, eliminating the incentive for inappropriate cost
shifting.
23. Following the same logic, we decline to adopt AT&T's proposal
that we require electing carriers to exit the National Exchange Carrier
Association (NECA) tariff pool for their ``switched and special access
services to avoid additional complexities in the annual tariff review
process and to avoid potential gaming.'' As Petitioners argue, AT&T
``fails to explain how any cost shifting would be useful given the
switched access rules [that cap rates].'' Moreover, the scrutiny
inherent in the part 61 tariff review process helps reduce the risk of
cost-shifting or other gaming by pool participants. We do, however,
require electing carriers currently participating in the NECA traffic-
sensitive tariff pool for their BDS or special access service offerings
to remove their BDS and special access offerings from the pool since
those services will be subject to incentive regulation.
24. We find that the lighter touch regulatory framework we adopt
provides electing carriers the right balance of relief from the
burdensome aspects of rate-of-return regulation and pricing discipline.
The efficiencies gained from reducing regulatory burdens on electing
carriers, including the increased flexibility to compete in the market,
will foster network investment and impose downward pressure on prices.
We also find here, as we did in the BDS Order, that ``minimiz[ing]
unnecessary government intervention . . . allows market forces to
continue working to spur entry, innovation, and competition.''
B. Applying Voluntary Incentive Regulation to Electing Carriers' Lower
Speed TDM Transport and End User Channel Termination Services
25. In this section, we provide direction on implementing the
voluntary incentive regulation we adopt today for electing carriers'
lower capacity (i.e., at or below a DS3-level) TDM transport and end
user channel termination services as part of our comprehensive lighter
touch regulatory framework for electing carriers' BDS. We treat
electing carriers' lower capacity TDM transport and end user channel
terminations differently from packet-based and higher speed TDM-based
BDS offerings because the record shows that packet-based offerings are
subject to competition that will ensure just and reasonable rates for
those services. By contrast, the record shows that demand for lower
speed TDM-based transport and end user channel terminations services is
shrinking as purchasers increasingly prefer higher speed and packet-
based services. Recognizing that the market is transitioning to new
technologies, we provide protections for lower speed TDM-based
transport and end user channel termination services. Based on the
current record, we preserve ex ante pricing regulation for lower speed
TDM-based transport services and adopt a competitive market test that
will preserve ex ante pricing regulation in those study areas where we
predict there is a substantial likelihood that competition will fail to
ensure just and reasonable rates for the lower capacity TDM-based end
user channel termination services.
26. Rate-of-return carriers that make this election will convert to
incentive regulation for their lower capacity TDM transport and end
user channel termination services as well as other generally lower
capacity non-packet-based services that are commonly considered special
access services. Specifically, among other matters, we adopt a
methodology for electing carriers to set their initial rates, allow an
unfreeze of separations category relationships for carriers that
elected to freeze them in 2001, adopt a productivity factor and measure
of inflation to adjust rates, and grant pricing flexibility to electing
carriers for their lower capacity TDM services.
1. Initial Rate Levels
27. First, we adopt the methodology electing carriers must use to
establish rates for their lower capacity TDM transport and end user
channel termination services pursuant to incentive regulation. For
rate-of-return carriers that file their own tariffed rates, we adopt
the approach proposed in the NPRM to set initial BDS rate levels based
on rates in effect on January 1, 2019 for carriers converting to
incentive regulation as of July 1, 2019 and on rates in effect on
January 1, 2020 for carriers that elect incentive regulation effective
as of July 1, 2020. For rate-of-return carriers participating in the
NECA traffic-sensitive tariff pool that elect incentive regulation
effective July 1, 2019, we adopt the approach proposed in the NPRM for
members exiting the pool to set their initial BDS rate levels by
adjusting NECA pool rates in effect on January 1, 2019 by a net
contribution or net recipient factor. Carriers electing incentive
regulation as of July 1, 2020 must set their initial BDS rate levels by
adjusting NECA pool rates in effect on January 1, 2020. Electing
carriers will then adjust their rates using a methodology that is
consistent with the price cap formulas in Sec. Sec. 61.45 to 61.47 of
our rules, by applying the productivity factor (X-factor), inflation
factor (Gross Domestic Product-Price Index (GDP-PI)), and any required
exogenous cost changes. Carriers may adjust these rates to reflect the
pricing flexibility permitted by the pricing bands in the Special
Access category.
28. Under rate-of-return regulation, incumbent LECs are permitted
to recover through tariffed rates their revenue requirement, which is
equal to their regulated operating costs plus a prescribed rate of
return on their regulated rate base. Rate-of-return carriers set rates
at levels that when
[[Page 67102]]
multiplied by demand will yield revenues equal to their revenue
requirement, and are targeted to earn the Commission's prescribed rate
of return. Rate-of-return carriers establish rates for BDS offerings
either by filing their own interstate access tariffs and cost support
pursuant to Sec. 61.38 or Sec. 61.39 of our rules or, for most rate-
of-return carriers, by participating in the NECA traffic-sensitive
tariff and traffic-sensitive pool. NECA sets the BDS rates in the
traffic-sensitive tariff based on projected aggregate costs (or average
schedule settlements) and demand of all pool members, which are
targeted to earn the authorized rate of return for NECA pool members.
29. When the Commission launched price cap regulation in 1990, it
found that interstate access rates as they existed on July 1, 1990, six
months prior to the date price caps went into effect on January 1,
1991, were the most reasonable basis from which to set initial rate
levels under price cap regulation. In other words, those rates created
the starting point for the indexing of rates under price cap
regulation--setting their price cap index, actual price index and
service band index at a value of 100. The price cap index is adjusted
by the productivity offset (X-factor) and inflation (GDP-PI) for the
first year, and each year thereafter. The Commission reasoned that
interstate rates that existed on July 1, 1990 ``while perhaps not
perfect, in general represent the best that rate-of-return regulation
can produce.''
30. Beginning with the Windstream Order, the Commission granted
several waivers allowing price cap carriers to convert their rate-of-
return study areas to price cap regulation. Carriers were, among other
things, required to establish initial price cap indexes using the rates
in effect on January 1 of the conversion year, six months prior to the
July 1 effective date of conversion, the demand from the preceding
year, and required to target their rates using the X-factor in effect
at that time. In the 2012 Average Schedule Conversion Order, the
Commission permitted several rate-of-return carriers to, among other
things, withdraw their average schedule study areas from the NECA pool
and convert them to price cap regulation. In that order, the Commission
approved a methodology for establishing initial price cap rates using
existing NECA pool tariffed rates adjusted to reflect the extent to
which the exiting study areas were either a net contributor to, or a
net recipient from, the NECA pool.
31. Carriers Currently Filing Their Own Tariffs. Consistent with
past practice, we adopt the proposal in the NPRM for carriers that
currently file their own tariffs to use existing tariffed rates to set
their initial BDS rates under incentive regulation. Carriers first will
set their price cap indexes based on their tariffed interstate special
access rates in effect on January 1, 2019, or based on those rates in
effect on January 1, 2020 for carriers electing to convert to incentive
regulation effective July 1, 2020. The price cap indexes (i.e., the
price cap index, actual price index, and service band index) will be
assigned values of 100 as starting points, which correspond to rate
levels in effect on January 1, 2019 or on January 1, 2020, as
applicable. Carriers then will adjust the price cap index and the
pricing band limits for each service category or subcategory consistent
with Sec. Sec. 61.45 through 61.47 of our rules, by applying the X-
factor (2.0%), inflation factor (GDP-PI), and any required exogenous
cost changes. Carriers, next, will set rates so that the actual price
index, calculated pursuant to Sec. 61.46, does not exceed the price
cap index, and the service band indexes for each service category or
subcategory, calculated pursuant to Sec. 61.47, do not exceed the
pricing band limits for each category or subcategory, for the first
year of incentive regulation and each year thereafter.
32. Carriers Participating in NECA Pool. We also adopt the approach
proposed in the NPRM for electing carrier study areas exiting the NECA
traffic-sensitive tariff pool to establish their initial BDS rates
under incentive regulation by multiplying the NECA pool rate in effect
on January 1, 2019 by a net contribution or net recipient factor or by
doing so using the NECA pool rate in effect on January 1, 2020 for
carriers electing conversion in 2020. No commenters opposed this
proposal. Electing carriers exiting the NECA pool will adjust the NECA
pool rate to reflect the extent they are either a net contributor or
net recipient in order to ensure their rates are just and reasonable.
Each NECA pool member receives a settlement from the pool based on its
costs plus a pro rata share of the earnings, or based on its settlement
pursuant to the average schedule formulas. NECA pool rates are lower
than necessary for a net recipient to recover its revenue requirement,
or higher than necessary for a net contributor to recover its revenue
requirement and must be adjusted by the extent to which the existing
study area is a net contributor to, or net recipient from, the NECA
pool in order to satisfy the just and reasonable standard. Without an
adjustment, electing carriers' BDS rates would be either artificially
high or low going forward.
33. First, to determine the appropriate net contributor or net
recipient factor, electing carriers exiting the pool effective July 1,
2019 will determine their interstate special access revenue for the
period July 1 to December 31, 2018. An electing carrier exiting the
NECA tariff shall determine its pool settlements to be used in
developing the factor based on costs for the period July 1 through
December 31, 2018, which reflects the first six months of tariff year
2018-19, the 12-month period for which the costs underlying the January
1, 2019 rates were projected. The pool settlements shall be adjusted to
reflect the 10.5% rate of return which was used to establish the
revenue requirement for the January 1, 2019 rates. Second, carriers
will calculate the difference between the exiting pool member's
interstate special access revenues for July 1 to December 31, 2018 and
special access pool settlements reflecting the authorized rate of
return for this same period. Third, this net contribution or net
recipient amount will then be divided by interstate special access
revenues for the same period to produce a percent net contribution or
net recipient factor. Fourth, carriers shall proportionately adjust
their special access NECA pool rates in effect on January 1, 2019
downward by the net contribution factor or upward by the net recipient
factor. Finally, carriers will adjust these rates further consistent
with Sec. Sec. 61.45 through 61.47 of our rules, in the manner
described above for carriers that file their own tariffs, to set their
initial BDS rates for the first year of incentive regulation. Carriers
electing to exit the NECA pool effective July 1, 2020 will use the same
methodology to adjust their rates but using the corresponding dates
that are one year later.
34. We agree with Petitioners that recommend that initial rates be
based on the existing tariffed rates at the time of a carrier's
election of incentive regulation. AT&T and Sprint disagree and argue
that the Commission should adjust initial BDS rates to account for the
rate-of-return transition that is currently underway. The Commission
adopted a six-year transition in 2016 to reduce the then-11.25% rate of
return by 25 basis points per year until the rate of return reaches
9.75% in 2021. AT&T and Sprint argue that the Commission should adjust
electing carriers' initial BDS rates to reflect the fully-transitioned
9.75% rate of return or, at a minimum, Sprint argues that the
[[Page 67103]]
Commission should adjust the price capped rates each year during the
rate-of-return transition until it ends in 2021. AT&T claims that
``[s]etting electing A-CAM carriers' initial rate-of-return at the
9.75% level immediately upon converting to price cap, while not
completely correcting, would help alleviate any rate disparities and
aligns with the Commission's finding that a 9.75% rate of return is
more than reasonable.''
35. We find that existing tariffed rates targeting the transitional
10.5% rate of return in effect is the more appropriate rate from which
to launch incentive regulation for carriers electing to convert to
incentive regulation effective July 1, 2019. AT&T and Sprint fail to
accord any significance to the Commission's decision to implement
changes in the prescribed rate of return over six years and the reasons
for such a measured and lengthy transition. In granting a six-year
transition, the Commission acknowledged that ``for almost 25 years,
rate-of-return carriers have made significant infrastructure
investments . . . and that represcribing the rate of return will have a
financial impact on these carriers.'' Rate-of-return carriers' business
plans and long-term capital investments are typically based on an
expected multi-year revenue stream. The Commission determined that an
immediate transition to a 9.75% rate of return would disrupt these
carriers' reasonable reliance on these expected revenues. The
Commission also recognized that ``rate-of-return incumbent LECs have
been subject to significant regulatory changes in recent years, and
that such changes are occurring at a time when these carriers are
attempting to transition their networks and service offerings to a
broadband world.'' Reflecting the balance of the six-year transition
whether through a one-time adjustment, or through a series of three
adjustments, would abandon this careful transition and would likely
disrupt electing carriers' ability to invest in upgrading and
transitioning their networks to provide broadband in the rural
communities they serve.
36. We also find that once a carrier elects incentive regulation,
its rates should be based on that form of regulation and not
effectively a hybrid or combination of rate-of-return and incentive
regulation, which would be the result were we to adopt the annual
adjustment the Commission has applied to carriers that are subject to
cost-based rate-of-return regulation as proposed by Sprint. Capping BDS
rates of an electing carrier that will be subject to incentive
regulation and reducing them annually by the X-factor going forward
will be sufficient to ensure these rates are just and reasonable while
at the same time creating the right incentives to operate efficiently--
a goal we cannot expect to achieve by continuing to overlay rate-of-
return obligations on top of an incentive regulation scheme. An annual
25 basis point adjustment would also be more administratively
burdensome to implement. Rather than perpetuating policies associated
with an inefficient rate-of-return system, we look to the ongoing
operation of incentive regulation to spur carriers to be more efficient
and productive than they were under rate-of-return regulation using X-
factor-based rate reductions.
37. Finally, as some commenters explain, reducing initial BDS rate
levels to account for the rate-of-return transition would ``reduce the
motivation of a carrier to opt into incentive regulation'' contrary to
the goals of this Order and the Commission's preference for incentive-
based regulation. If initial BDS rates were adjusted to the fully-
transitioned rate of return of 9.75%, carriers would be able to earn a
higher return and revenue during the rate-of-return regulation
transition that ends in 2021 than by moving to incentive regulation.
This outcome is contrary to the Commission's long-standing policy
preferring incentive-based regulation over rate-of-return regulation
and encouraging conversions to incentive-based regulation. Incentive
regulation will encourage electing carriers to be more efficient than
they were under rate-of-return regulation, and pass some of these
efficiencies on to consumers through rate reductions (or rates that are
lower than otherwise) through the application of a price cap formula
that reflects a properly calculated X-factor. Accordingly, we seek to
encourage carriers to adopt incentive regulation by allowing electing
carriers to set their initial rates under incentive regulation based on
rates reflecting the transitional rate of return currently in effect.
38. We agree with Petitioners that initial rates for lower capacity
TDM transport and end user channel termination services should be based
on existing tariffed deemed lawful rates--rates that target the
effective transitional rate of return. We therefore set initial rates
for carriers electing to convert to incentive regulation as of July 1,
2019 for lower capacity TDM transport and end user channel termination
services based on electing carriers' tariffed rates in effect on
January 1, 2019, six months prior to when incentive regulation goes
into effect on July 1, 2019. Similarly, initial rates for carriers
electing to convert to incentive regulation as of July 1, 2020 will be
based on the tariffed rates in effect on January 1, 2020. Existing
tariffed rates filed pursuant to section 204(a)(3) of the Act that take
effect, without prior suspension and investigation, are deemed lawful
and conclusively presumed to be just and reasonable. Setting initial
rates based on existing tariffed rates, as noted by commenters, is
``consistent with the methodologies used in the past when rate-of-
return carriers have converted to price cap regulation.'' Further, the
selection of tariffed rates in effect on a date that precedes the
effective date of incentive regulation helps prevent rapid aggregate
price increases in the period leading up to the incentive regulation
that would inflate price cap baseline rates. Accordingly, price cap
indexes under incentive regulation will be initially set at a value of
100 based on rates in effect on January 1, 2019 for carriers electing
incentive regulation as of July 1, 2019, and on rates in effect on
January 1, 2020 for carriers electing incentive regulation as of July
1, 2020. Business data services rates for carriers accepting future
offers of A-CAM support or otherwise transition away from legacy
support mechanisms will be effective on July 1 in the year following
their election.
2. Category Relationships Unfreeze
39. We give electing carriers subject to the category relationships
freeze of our separations rules, including any such carriers that
accept future offers of A-CAM support or otherwise transition away from
legacy support mechanisms, the opportunity to opt out of that freeze.
We agree with Petitioners and WTA that the category relationships
freeze creates a cost recovery hardship for certain carriers and a
distortion in rates that should not be incorporated into rates that
electing carriers set for lower capacity circuit-based business data
services under incentive regulation.
40. Background. Rate-of-return incumbent LECs use their networks
and other resources to provide both interstate and intrastate services.
The Commission's part 36 jurisdictional separations rules are designed
to help prevent the recovery of the same costs from both the interstate
and intrastate jurisdictions and require that rate-of-return incumbent
LECs divide their costs and revenues between the respective
jurisdictions. The jurisdictional separations analysis begins with
categorizing the incumbent LEC's regulated costs and revenues, a
process requiring that the incumbent LEC assign the regulated
investments, expenses, and revenues recorded in its part 32 accounts to
various part 36
[[Page 67104]]
categories. The incumbent LEC then directly assigns to the interstate
or intrastate jurisdiction, or allocates between those jurisdictions,
the costs or revenues in each part 36 category.
41. In 1997, the Commission initiated a proceeding to
comprehensively reform its jurisdictional separations rules and
referred that matter to the Federal-State Joint Board on Jurisdictional
Separations (Joint Board) for preparation of a recommended decision. In
the 2001 Separations Freeze Order, 66 FR 33202, June 21, 2001, the
Commission froze the jurisdictional separations rules to allow time for
the Joint Board to develop recommendations on comprehensive separations
reform. Also, in that Order, the Commission granted rate-of-return
carriers a one-time option to freeze their category relationships,
enabling each carrier to determine whether such a freeze would be
beneficial ``based on its own circumstances and investment plans.''
Carriers that elected this freeze assign regulated costs to separations
categories based on separations category relationships from 2001,
rather than on current data. Presently, approximately 28 rate-of-return
carriers that receive fixed high-cost universal service support operate
under this category relationships freeze.
42. The Commission has repeatedly extended the separations freeze.
The most recent extension is set to expire on December 31, 2018. In the
2018 Separations Freeze Extension proceeding, the Commission proposed
to extend the separations freeze for 15 years, while providing a one-
time opportunity for carriers that had elected to freeze their category
relationships to opt out of that freeze and categorize their costs
based on current data rather than separations category results from
2001. The Commission has not yet acted on that proposal.
43. Category Relationships Unfreeze. The category relationships
freeze has now been in place for more than 17 years, and our rules
prohibit carriers that elected that freeze from withdrawing from it.
Rate-of-return carriers that chose to freeze their category
relationships in 2001 assign costs within part 32 accounts to
categories using their separations category relationships from 2000.
This means that these companies are still separating their costs based
on the technologies and services that were in place in 2000, instead of
being able to adjust the amounts assigned to separations categories to
reflect the current network costs and services that would allow these
carriers to properly recover their costs. Investment by carriers is
becoming more weighted toward BDS and away from switched access and
common line categories. Thus, we agree with Petitioners that the result
is that some, if not all, carriers with frozen category relationships
are unable to recover their BDS costs from BDS customers or from NECA
traffic sensitive pool settlements.
44. We therefore allow electing carriers to unfreeze and update
their category relationships in conjunction with setting their initial
rates, which will enable such carriers to more closely align their BDS
rates with their underlying costs as they set initial incentive
regulation rates. Once an electing carrier implements incentive
regulation rates for its BDS, it will no longer need to comply with the
separations rules by virtue of our action below forbearing from
application of the separations and other cost assignment rules to
electing carriers. This, in turn, will allow the carriers and their
customers to benefit from the efficiencies of incentive regulation.
45. The Commission originally allowed rate-of-return carriers the
flexibility to choose whether to freeze their category relationships
because those carriers' size, cost structures, and investment patterns
vary widely. For similar reasons, we conclude that the burden on
electing carriers, were we to require all impacted carriers to unfreeze
and update their category relationships, would outweigh any benefits,
and thus grant these carriers the flexibility to choose. For example,
some carriers may have based their current business plans and
investment on a continuation of the freeze since it has been in effect
for such a long period and compelling these carriers to unfreeze their
categories now could be disruptive. Further, it would impose a
disproportionate burden on companies with cost structures that have not
changed significantly enough to warrant the administrative costs that
these carriers would incur in updating their relationships. Moreover,
the process of unfreezing and updating category relationships is
resource-intensive, requiring carriers to develop detailed analyses for
new categorization cost studies. As a result, we recognize that some
electing carriers may choose not to unfreeze their category
relationships in conjunction with setting initial incentive regulation
rates for lower capacity circuit-based business data services because
of the administrative costs they would incur in updating these
relationships. We see no need to require that electing carriers incur
these costs, particularly since one of the principal goals of this
proceeding is to reduce unnecessary regulatory burdens.
46. In adopting this option, we reject NARUC's contention that we
are violating section 410(c) of the Communications Act by failing to
meaningfully consult with, and receive a recommendation from the Joint
Board. Section 410(c) applies only to the extent the Commission engages
in ``the jurisdictional separation of common carrier property and
expenses between interstate and intrastate operations.'' Here, we are
not engaged in that process. Instead, we are determining which costs
electing carriers should use to calculate their incentive regulation
rates for lower capacity circuit-based BDS. In allowing electing
carriers to set those rates using data from 2018, rather than 2000, we
make no change to the jurisdictional separations rules.
47. As set forth more fully below, we direct each electing carrier
that chooses to update its separations category relationships to
conduct two cost studies for 2018 and to use those cost studies in
determining its initial incentive regulation rates. In so doing, we are
exercising our authority over interstate rates and are not in any way
requiring state commissions to make similar intrastate adjustments. On
the contrary, our forbearance from application of the separations rules
to electing carriers will allow the states to adopt their own rules for
determining the costs carriers incur in providing intrastate services
to the extent they have authority under state law.
48. Moreover, even if we were to interpret 410(c) so broadly as to
be applicable to the opportunity we provide electing carriers to
unfreeze their category relationships, our actions are not in conflict
with our obligations under section 410(c). In 2009, the Commission
asked the Joint Board to consider whether the Commission should allow
carriers a one-time opportunity to unfreeze their separations category
relationships and requested that the Joint Board prepare a recommended
decision on that matter. No recommendation has been forthcoming.
Section 410(c) directs that, after a referral, the Joint Board ``shall
prepare a recommended decision for prompt review and action by the
Commission.'' Nothing in section 410(c) obligates the Commission to
wait indefinitely for a recommended decision before acting. We conclude
that the only reasonable interpretation of this statutory language
allows the Commission to act unilaterally where, as here, an issue has
been pending before the Joint Board for more than nine years without a
recommended decision. Any contrary interpretation would allow the Joint
Board to
[[Page 67105]]
indefinitely delay Commission action. Congress could not have intended
that result while requiring that that the Commission act promptly once
the Joint Board issues a recommended decision.
49. Section 410(c) also requires that the Commission ``afford the
State members of the Joint Board an opportunity to participate in its
deliberations'' on ``decisional action[s]'' regarding matters that have
been referred to the Joint Board. To the extent this provision can be
read as applying to this proceeding, the notice and comment periods and
permit-but-disclose rules governing this proceeding have provided
plenty of opportunity for the state members of the Joint Board to voice
their opinions on allowing electing carriers to opt out of the category
relationships freeze.
50. Implementation. To ensure that updated category relationships
are properly reflected in incentive regulation rates, we require each
electing carrier that chooses to update its frozen category
relationships to conduct two 2018 cost studies--one based on frozen
category relationships and one based on unfrozen relationships. To
determine its incentive regulation rates for BDS, the carrier shall
divide the BDS costs under the revised 2018 cost study by the BDS costs
determined in the original 2018 cost study using frozen category
relationships to develop a rate adjustment factor. The carrier shall
apply this factor to the initial (prior to adjustments for the X-
factor, inflation factor, and any exogenous cost changes) rates
established in accordance with the procedures explained elsewhere in
this Order to set the carrier's initial rates for lower capacity
circuit-based BDS under incentive regulation. The carrier shall adjust
these rates for the X-factor, inflation factor, and any exogenous cost
changes and may adjust these rates to reflect any pricing flexibility
allowed among services within the special access basket. Carriers that
elect incentive regulation effective as of July 1, 2020 will follow
these directions, except that if an electing carrier chooses to update
its frozen category relationships it will conduct two 2019 cost studies
and use the results of these cost studies to complete the steps
described in this paragraph.
51. Unfreezing separations category relationships could result in a
carrier recovering the same costs through higher BDS rates and
unchanged switched access recovery. Incorporating updated category
relationships into the 2018 cost study, or 2019 cost study for carriers
electing the January 1, 2020 effective date, will change the costs
assigned to the switched access category just as it will for BDS. The
USF/ICC Transformation Order capped all interstate switched access
rates at 2011 levels, subject to specified reductions over time. We do
not permit electing carriers to increase their switched access rate
caps. Unless cost reductions to interstate switched access are
reflected in a carrier's revised base period revenue amount, a carrier
will double-recover costs through its interstate switched access rates.
To account for this effect, an electing carrier that unfreezes its
separations category relationships must calculate the difference
between the interstate switched access costs in the two 2018 cost
studies. Each electing carrier must adjust its base period revenue by
an amount equal to the interstate switched access cost difference
between the two 2018 cost studies before applying the annual 5%
reduction to the base period revenue. This is the process that the
Commission employed in the Eastex proceeding. Carriers electing a
January 1, 2020 effective date will do the same with 2019 cost studies.
52. An electing carrier that participates in the NECA interstate
switched access tariff must report to NECA the interstate switched
access cost difference between the two 2018, or, 2019, studies and its
revised base period revenue amount. These procedures protect both
carriers and customers from any unintended consequences of moving BDS
from rate-of-return regulation to incentive regulation. Any electing
carrier that opts out of the category relationships freeze shall
include, in its 2019 or 2020, respectively, annual filing, workpapers
showing how it implemented the measures set forth above. This does not
eliminate the need for an electing carrier to adjust its Eligible
Recovery for any other instances of double recovery. Finally, we
require NECA to reflect these base period revenue changes in its
settlement procedures.
53. We find that these measures provide a reasonable and not unduly
burdensome method for ensuring that costs shifted from an electing
carrier's unfreezing of its category relationships are carried forward
into its incentive regulation rates for BDS without any double-
recovery. Each electing carrier that chooses to update its category
relationships will necessarily need to perform detailed calculations to
implement that choice. We minimize the associated burdens by specifying
that the electing carrier adjust its business data service rates to
account for the changes in the category relationships using the 2018
cost study, or the 2019 cost study for carriers electing to convert
effective July 1, 2020, that this Order requires of all electing
carriers and therefore will impose only a minimal incremental burden on
electing carriers.
3. Special Access Basket, Categories, and Subcategories
54. We retain the special access basket, categories and
subcategories, and the attendant rules governing the allowed annual
rate adjustments for price cap regulation for incentive regulation.
Commenting parties support this approach. The category and sub-category
requirements limit the degree to which a carrier can raise rates for
particular groups of services in any given year. Each electing carrier
that elects incentive regulation must set its initial price cap indexes
for the special access basket and associated service band indices at
100 and use the rate adjustment rules for price cap carriers contained
in Sec. Sec. 61.45 to 61.48 of our rules, as appropriate, to reflect
the prescribed productivity factor, the inflation factor, and any
required exogenous cost adjustment in the price cap index. These steps
will ensure that the carrier's actual price index does not exceed its
price cap index, and that its service band indexes for each category or
subcategory do not exceed their upper limits.
4. Productivity X-Factor and Measure of Inflation
55. Consistent with the price cap BDS Order, we adopt 2.0% as the
productivity factor (X-factor) and the Gross Domestic Product-Price
Index (GDP-PI) as the inflation factor used to adjust price cap indexes
in the first year of incentive regulation, and each year thereafter. As
proposed in the NPRM, we decline to incorporate a consumer productivity
dividend adjustment into the X-factor.
56. Background. Under price cap regulation, the price cap index
seeks to replicate the beneficial cost-reducing incentives of a
competitive market by limiting the prices that a price cap LEC may
charge for services. After price cap carriers set initial price cap
indexes based on going-in rate levels, these indexes are adjusted
annually based primarily on the productivity factor (X-factor) and
inflation factor (GDP-PI) as well as any exogenous cost adjustments.
The X-factor adjustment is intended to capture the amount by which
incumbent LECs could be expected to outperform economy-wide
productivity gains and to pass those gains on to consumers in the form
of lower prices. In the past, the Commission has also
[[Page 67106]]
applied a consumer productivity dividend adjustment to the X-factor to
capture for ratepayers a portion of the benefits from expected
productivity gains exceeding those incumbent LECs had historically
achieved under rate-of-return regulation. The inflation factor is
intended to adjust prices to capture economy-wide rates of inflation.
Historically, the Commission has used the U.S. Department of Commerce's
Bureau of Economic Analysis's GDP-PI, a chain-weighted index of overall
national prices, as the inflation factor.
57. In the BDS Order, the Commission adopted for price cap carriers
a 2.0% productivity-based X-factor and retained GDP-PI as the inflation
factor but declined to apply a consumer productivity dividend
adjustment. The Commission found that 2.0% reflects its best estimate
of the productivity growth that incumbent LECs will experience in the
provision of BDS services relative to productivity growth in the
overall economy. To determine the X-factor, the Commission applied a
total factor productivity methodology, which measures the relationship
between the output of goods and services to inputs. The Commission
applied this methodology to the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics'
Capital, Labor, Energy, Materials, and Services (KLEMS) dataset for the
broadcasting and telecommunications industries for estimating incumbent
LEC productivity and input prices. The Commission used these data to
establish a zone of reasonable X-factor estimates based on four
relevant time periods, and from this zone selected an X-factor of 2.0%.
The Commission also retained GDP-PI as the measure of inflation.
Accordingly, price cap LECs adjust their price cap indexes annually by
the 2.0% X-factor and GDP-PI to ensure just and reasonable rates for
these BDS services.
58. Discussion. Consistent with the BDS Order, we adopt 2.0% as the
productivity factor electing carriers will use to adjust their price
cap indexes. In so doing, we reaffirm the Commission's finding in the
BDS Order that the 2.0% X-factor represents our best estimate of BDS
productivity gains or losses relative to the general economy and is a
reasonable productivity factor with which to adjust price cap indexes
for purposes of incentive regulation.
59. WTA opposes adoption of the 2.0% productivity X-factor for
incentive regulation, contending that ``given increasing broadband-
related labor costs and the fact that the typical WTA member has only
10-to-20 employees, it does not appear possible for many small A-CAM
and Alaska Plan companies to achieve productivity gains of two percent
each year.'' We believe, however, that the 2.0% X-factor is the most
reliable estimate of BDS productivity growth for carriers generally,
including smaller carriers. The 2.0% X-factor was the product of an
economically-sound total factor productivity methodology, consistent
with past Commission practice, using the only reliable and internally
consistent dataset in the record in the BDS proceeding, KLEMS, for
measuring incumbent LEC productivity and input prices. WTA focuses on
one type of input price--labor costs--for which KLEMS captures
telecommunications industry trends, including broadband-related trends,
for carriers of all sizes. WTA implicitly assumes that its members'
labor costs will rise more quickly (or fall more slowly) than price cap
carriers' labor costs. Even if we were to accept this assumption, WTA
does not address whether other factors affecting BDS productivity
growth, such as changes in BDS demand, offset any disparity in the rate
of change in labor costs.
60. The Commission sought comment on alternative X-factors for
electing carriers but received no data or other information that would
allow us to calculate an alternative X-factor. And while WTA provides
anecdotal data on a selected portion of its members' costs, it has
``not submitted the company-specific input price and output data that
we would need to quantify'' the extent to which its members'
productivity growth and ability to recover costs deviate from the
industry average. In the BDS Order, the Commission declined to adjust
the X-factor to account for conflicting and unquantifiable evidence in
the record that the KLEMS dataset overstated or understated
productivity growth. And the Eighth Circuit Court of Appeals upheld the
Commission's decision not to adjust the KLEMS dataset ``in light of the
conflicting evidence on what sort of adjustment was appropriate.'' In
these circumstances, we see no valid basis on which to adopt an
alternative X-factor.
61. Notwithstanding WTA's concerns, we believe that most electing
carriers will be able to achieve the 2.0% X-factor. Petitioners support
our use of a 2.0% X-factor, even though they state that rate-of-return
carriers may generally achieve lower productivity growth than price cap
carriers, and TDS Telecom endorses the regulatory framework adopted in
the BDS Order that includes a 2.0% X-factor. Given that rate-of-return
carriers receiving fixed support are not required to move to incentive
regulation, carriers unable to achieve the 2.0% X-factor will avoid any
harm by simply not electing incentive regulation. The voluntary nature
of incentive regulation therefore renders moot any risk involved in
attempting today to determine what an appropriate productivity factor
would be for this group of carriers. Carriers themselves are in the
best position to determine whether they will benefit from incentive
regulation and we have afforded them that flexibility.
62. Inflation Factor. We adopt GDP-PI as the inflation factor as
proposed in the NPRM. No commenter opposed this proposal. As we found
in the BDS Order, there is no alternative measure of inflation
presented in the record that is as accurate as GDP-PI in the medium-
and long-term and that is not susceptible to carrier influence or
manipulation. Accordingly, electing carriers will adjust their price
cap indexes by GDP-PI during the first year of incentive regulation,
and each year thereafter.
63. Consumer Productivity Dividend. We decline to incorporate a
consumer productivity dividend adjustment into the X-factor adopted in
this Order. No commenter opposed this proposal in the NPRM. In the BDS
Order, the Commission found that the 2.0% X-factor reflected all
anticipated future BDS productivity growth and declined to include a
consumer productivity dividend adjustment in the X-factor. For similar
reasons, and to avoid regulatory disparity with price cap regulation,
we decline to include a consumer productivity dividend in the X-factor
for incentive regulation.
5. Exogenous Costs
64. After reviewing the record, we adopt the proposal in the NPRM
that exogenous costs be allocated based on a ratio of BDS revenues to
total revenues from all regulated services and an electing carrier's
universal service support payments. Exogenous costs are those costs
that are beyond the control of the carrier, as determined by the
Commission. We agree with Petitioners that allowing exogenous cost
adjustments is appropriate. When costs are beyond the carrier's
control, they are often of a nature that is not reflected in the
measurement of productivity. It is therefore appropriate to allow
adjustments to reflect exogenous events upon Commission approval.
65. We reject Sprint's proposal that any exogenous cost changes
should be limited by applying the ratio of BDS revenues to total
enterprise revenues. Sprint does not define ``total enterprise
revenues'' or explain why it would result in a more relevant comparison
to BDS revenues than using total regulated
[[Page 67107]]
revenues, and we find it too expansive for use here. The exogenous
costs being allocated are those associated with regulated services as
determined by the part 64 allocation rules for assigning costs
associated with non-regulated activities. Thus, we find that regulated
BDS revenues compared to all regulated revenues and related support
receipts is the most relevant relationship to allocate a portion of
exogenous costs related to regulated services to BDS.
66. Finally, we will not require electing carriers to incur the
costs of filing a short form tariff review plan as price cap carriers
are required to do. In recent years, the Bureau has waived the
requirement that price cap LECs file the short form, finding that it
would provide little value to the Commission, industry, and consumers.
We find that the short form tariff review plan would also provide
little value to the Commission, industry, and consumers in conjunction
with incentive regulation for electing carriers. We accordingly do not
require its filing.
6. Low-end Adjustment
67. We adopt the low-end adjustment mechanism proposed in the NPRM
to provide an appropriate backstop to ensure that electing carriers are
not subject to protracted periods of low earnings. A below-normal rate
of return over a prolonged period could threaten a carrier's ability to
raise the capital necessary to provide modern, efficient services to
customers. The low-end adjustment mechanism will permit a one-time
adjustment to a single year's BDS rates to avoid back-to-back annual
earnings below a set benchmark. This course should allow electing
carriers to meet their existing obligations to debtholders and attract
sufficient capital while continuing to provide BDS.
68. We reject Sprint's argument that any low-end adjustment should
be allowed only if a sharing mechanism is adopted for a carrier's
earnings. A sharing mechanism is a process that allocates a portion of
a carrier's excess earnings under price cap regulation to the consumer
through a one-time reduction in a carrier's price cap index. The
Commission eliminated the sharing mechanism for price cap carriers in
1997. There is no causal link between the low-end adjustment mechanism
and earnings sharing, and the two have not previously been tied
together in other incentive regulation programs. The BDS Order allowed
a low-end adjustment without a sharing mechanism and Sprint provides no
convincing basis for diverging from that approach.
69. We use 100 basis points below the authorized rate of return for
rate-of-return carriers as the benchmark for establishing the low-end
adjustment as we did in the BDS Order. This approach will approximate
the transition to the authorized rate of return of 9.75%. A carrier
asserting a claim for a low-end adjustment bears the burden of showing
that its return is below the prescribed benchmark and that the revised
rate(s) are consistent with the benchmark.
70. Finally, as the Commission proposed in the NPRM, electing
carriers that exercise downward pricing flexibility (for example, by
entering into a contract tariff with a customer), or use generally
accepted accounting principles (GAAP) rather than the part 32 Uniform
System of Accounts, will be ineligible for a low-end adjustment. No
party has opposed this limitation to the availability of the low-end
adjustment mechanism. This limitation is consistent with that imposed
in the BDS Order, and we see no reason to diverge from that approach
here.
7. Pricing Flexibility for Lower Capacity TDM Transport and End User
Channel Termination Services
71. We adopt the proposal in the NPRM to grant pricing flexibility
to electing carriers for their lower capacity TDM transport and end
user channel termination services under incentive regulation similar to
the pricing flexibility the Commission granted to price cap carriers'
lower capacity TDM end user channel terminations in areas deemed non-
competitive. We agree with commenters that permitting electing carriers
to offer contract tariff pricing and volume and term discounts will
benefit both carriers and customers and will promote competition in
electing carriers' BDS markets. Requiring that electing carriers also
maintain generally available tariff rates for their lower capacity TDM
transport and end user channel termination services will ensure that
the rates of customers that do not negotiate contract-based or term and
volume discounted rates for such services will continue to be just and
reasonable. Additionally, we condition this grant of pricing
flexibility on the requirement that electing carriers remove contract
tariff demand from the relevant incentive regulation basket for
purposes of determining their price cap indexes and actual price
indexes, which will ensure that those customers that do not negotiate
contract tariffs will not cross-subsidize customers that do.
C. Removal of Ex Ante Pricing Regulation of Lower Capacity TDM End User
Channel Termination Services in Areas Deemed Competitive
72. As part of our framework for moving electing carriers to less
intrusive pricing regulation of their BDS offerings, we adopt a
competitive market test to identify those areas served by electing
carriers where competition or potential competition for lower speed
(DS3 or less) TDM end user channel termination services justifies
removing ex ante pricing regulation for those services. In adopting a
competitive market test for electing carriers, we are guided by the
Commission's previous work in developing a competitive market test for
price cap carriers' BDS offerings. At the same time, we are persuaded
by commenters that argue that the competitive market test should rely
on evidence of competition in the study areas served by electing
carriers.
73. We adopt a competitive market test for electing carriers that
is based on a modified version of the second prong of the BDS Order
competitive market test, which uses publicly available Form 477 data to
measure whether a cable operator offers a minimum of 10/1 Mbps in 75%
of census blocks in a study area served by a price cap provider. We
will apply this test in electing carriers' study areas, and in those
study areas deemed competitive by the competitive market test, we
remove ex ante pricing regulation of lower capacity TDM end user
channel terminations.
74. We are also constrained in the development of a competitive
market test by the limited availability of data in the record regarding
competition for BDS services in the study areas served by eligible
rate-of-return carriers. We decline, however, to adopt any of the
options we proposed in the NPRM for a competitive market test that
would require a new data collection. Commenters strongly oppose a new
information collection, arguing it would be burdensome and unnecessary.
We agree. A new information collection for electing carriers would be
especially burdensome given their relatively smaller size. The
Commission similarly declined to require a new data collection even for
larger price cap carriers in the BDS Order, as part of deciding to
update the price cap competitive market test results, finding that the
burdens would outweigh the benefits, and the burden of collecting the
information would be considerable. Additionally, the burdens associated
with an information collection could reduce incentives for eligible
carriers to elect incentive regulation, counter to
[[Page 67108]]
our goals. A simple, administrable test will ensure more resources are
available for competition and deployment in electing carriers' study
areas.
75. In the NPRM, we sought comment on whether to include lower
capacity TDM transport services in the competitive market test. Given
the lack of data in our record, we find that including such transport
services would be unworkable at this time. We therefore decline to
adopt a competitive market test for lower capacity TDM transport in
electing carriers' study areas.
1. Criteria for a Competitive Market Test
76. In this section, we address appropriate criteria for a
competitive market test for electing carriers' lower speed TDM end user
channel termination services, including the appropriate product market,
number of competitors in a market, and geographic market.
77. Product market. When defining a product market, to ensure our
action affects an appropriate group of services, we look to which
services are sufficiently similar to reasonably be considered
substitutes. We find the Commission's analysis of the relevant market
in the BDS Order to be applicable to the current situation, and,
therefore find the relevant product market includes circuit- and
packet-based business data services, legacy hybrid-fiber-coaxial, and
copper. For the same reason, we find that the product market also
includes unbundled network elements, dark fiber, and fixed wireless
services and facilities used to provision BDS. These services play
competitive roles in BDS markets. While the Commission did not find
best-efforts services to be close substitutes for all types of BDS in
the BDS Order, we acknowledge here as the Commission did there that
they nonetheless place a degree of competitive pressure on BDS
suppliers, particularly for lower capacity services. Further, we
believe a best-efforts supplier with its own ubiquitous wireline
network has strong incentives to supply BDS to locations where it
currently does not, and all the more so to the extent that an existing
supplier is charging supra-competitive prices. We also continue to
expect that suppliers exercising any short-term market power generally
will be constrained by supply-side substitution over the medium term
(3-5 years) in locations where other providers, such as cable
companies, offer best-efforts or other telecommunications services over
their own facilities. We therefore find that the product market
analysis that the Commission conducted for price cap areas in the BDS
Order applies equally to electing carrier areas.
78. Competition Within a Study Area. We must also determine the
appropriate level of competition for any competitive market test. The
Commission, in the BDS Order determined that a ``combination of either
one competitive provider with a network within a half mile from a
location served by an incumbent LEC or a cable operator's facilities in
the same census block as a location with demand will provide
competitive restraint'' more effectively than legacy regulation. The
Commission decided that a ``nearby'' BDS competitor provides sufficient
competition after analyzing three findings: (1) The geographic scope
within which a likely BDS provider can realistically compete with an
incumbent LEC; (2) a finding that one competitor in addition to the
incumbent LEC provides a reasonable degree of competition; and, (3) the
benefits of competition outweigh the potential unintended costs of
regulation.
79. We do not have data showing where there is a competitive
provider with a network half a mile from a location served by carriers
eligible to elect the lighter touch regulatory framework we adopt
today. We do, however, have Form 477 data which is organized on a
census block-level. We can therefore identify the census blocks served
by an electing carrier where cable broadband services are also
deployed. We find it appropriate to use cable broadband in the census
blocks that comprise the electing carrier's study area as a proxy for
competition because, as the Commission previously determined, ``cable
companies have focused investment on building fiber networks for
higher-bandwidth Ethernet services, which is enabling them to overcome
limitations of traditional coaxial-based cable systems that cannot meet
higher bandwidth demand.'' Cable providers have shifted to offering
``higher (and more competitive) bandwidths. At the same time, cable
operators' best efforts (and Ethernet over Hybrid Fiber-coaxial
(EoHFC)) services continue to compete effectively against incumbent
LECs' lower speed TDM services. The Commission also found that because
cable operators have ``aggressive[ly] deploy[ed]'' it was ``highly
likely the cable-only measure found in the Form 477 data will capture
the vast bulk of additional deployments; it is likely that most non-
cable competitive extension of business data services networks will
occur where cable is also deploying or has already deployed.'' This
rationale is equally applicable to electing carriers' provision of BDS
in their study areas.
80. As the Commission found in the BDS Order, and as the Eighth
Circuit Court affirmed, a single wireline competitor provides a
substantial competitive effect by disciplining rates, terms, and
conditions to just and reasonable levels. In industries with large sunk
costs, such as wireline providers, the largest impact occurs with the
entry of a second provider, with added benefits from additional
competitors declining thereafter. This is because the presence of a
nearby provider is likely to prevent or mitigate substantial abuse of
market power, either through lack of innovation or high prices. This
finding is not challenged in the record. Consistent with the analysis
in the BDS Order, we find that the effect of a single BDS competitor is
sufficient to limit anticompetitive behavior, and that the presence of
a cable network offering a minimum of 10/1 Mbps broadband service in
75% of the census blocks in a study area is sufficient to deem a study
area competitive for the purposes of the competitive market test for
electing carriers.
81. Geographic Market. We find that an electing carrier's
individual study area is the appropriate geographic market measure for
the competitive market test because it is administratively feasible but
is granular enough to capture reasonably similar competitive
conditions. A study area is a geographic segment of a rate-of-return
incumbent LEC's telephone operations that generally corresponds to the
carrier's entire service territory within a state. Incumbent LECs
determine eligibility for high-cost universal service support at the
study area level, perform jurisdictional separations at the study area
level and generally tariff their rates at the study area level. As a
result, the Commission and the industry have substantial experience
administering rules on a study area basis. What's more, a study area is
granular enough to capture reasonably similar competitive conditions.
Rate-of-return study areas vary in size but are significantly smaller
than metropolitan statistical areas and generally smaller than counties
and are therefore sufficiently granular to assess competitive
conditions. Given their mostly rural nature, the average size of a
rate-of-return study area is 992.82 square miles, compared to the
average county, 1,180.40 square miles, and the average metropolitan
statistical area, 2,720.95 square miles. Adopting study areas as the
geographic market also avoids risk of competitive overlap by, for
example, a rate-of-return study area
[[Page 67109]]
crossing county lines that are deemed competitive and noncompetitive.
82. We also reject other proposals in the record, including
suggestions to build a competitive market test for electing carriers
that uses counties or census blocks as the relevant geographic market.
We agree with Smithville that the selection of counties for use in the
price cap competitive market test was ``a well-documented effective
approach for competitive area evaluation for larger price cap carriers
that operate service areas dimensioned at statewide levels but does not
work well for carriers that have sub-county service areas.'' To the
extent such proposals seek to assess competition in electing carriers'
study areas based on competition elsewhere within the county, we reject
that proposition--any competitive market test must be based on the
competitive conditions each carrier faces, not those another carrier
faces somewhere else in a county. Additionally, some study areas cross
county lines. Using counties would potentially require us to subdivide
study areas along county boundaries, which would involve unreasonable
administrative burdens and could lead to varying treatment of a single
study area depending on the counties in which it is located.
83. In response to the 2017 Public Notice, Smithville argues that
using census blocks to assess competition in electing carriers' study
areas would be a better approach. We decline to adopt census blocks as
a geographic measure for our competitive market test. The Commission
previously found that census blocks or census tracts are too numerous
to efficiently administer. Additionally, they can be impacted by
changes in demand as small as a single building and could lead to a
patchwork of different regulations that vary from census block-to-
census block, or even building-to-building. Study areas, on the other
hand, are more administratively feasible because there are a limited
number of study areas eligible to elect our BDS regulatory framework.
2. Competitive Market Test Methodology
84. In this section, we describe the specific structure of the
electing carriers' competitive market test we adopt for electing
carriers' lower capacity TDM end user channel termination services. In
determining whether electing carriers with lower capacity TDM-based end
user channel termination services (at a DS3 or below), face sufficient
competition to allow competition, rather than ex ante pricing
regulation, to ensure rates are just and reasonable, we adopt a
competitive market test modeled on a modified version of the second
prong of the existing price cap competitive market test using data from
census blocks served by electing carriers. The second prong of the
price cap competitive market test uses Form 477 data to measure whether
a cable operator offers a minimum of 10/1 Mbps broadband service in 75%
of the census blocks in the price-cap service areas within a county.
Having decided that we will use only existing data to gauge competition
in the study areas served by an electing carrier, for purposes of the
electing carriers' competitive market test, if a cable operator or
other competitive provider offers a minimum of 10/1 Mbps broadband
service in 75% of the census blocks in an electing carrier's study
area, we will deem the study area competitive.
85. We set 10 Mbps downstream and 1 Mbps upstream as minimum
thresholds for a cable operator's service to be included in the
competitive market test. Setting a minimum threshold ensures that the
networks that supply these services are reasonable proxies for the type
of network facilities needed to deliver BDS. As we observed in the BDS
Order, ``when a cable provider is capable of providing internet
broadband service within any census block, then generally they have the
incentive to make the incremental investment necessary to serve
locations with BDS demand in that census block, especially over the
medium term.'' Cable operators are continuing to invest in and upgrade
the capacities of their networks, which give us reasonable assurance
that these networks will be capable of providing BDS competition over
the short- to medium-term. Additionally, the 10/1 Mbps threshold is
also the threshold that rate-of-return carriers accepting fixed A-CAM
support are required to offer to funded locations.
86. Using Form 477 data for electing carriers' study areas is
administratively simple for both the Commission and electing carriers.
We already regularly require providers to update their Form 477
submissions, so we do not need to undertake a new data collection.
Another benefit of the new electing carriers' competitive market test
is the incorporation of the 78 rate-of-return-only counties that cannot
be analyzed using the price cap competitive market test. Had we decided
to allow electing carriers to opt-in to the price cap competitive
market test, the competitive status of electing carriers serving any of
those 78 rate-of-return-only counties would have been unresolved
because they were not included in the original analysis.
87. We recognize that under the electing carriers' competitive
market test, a relatively small percentage of electing carriers' study
areas will be deemed competitive at this time. The current result of
the competitive market test we adopt today for rate-of-return carriers
receiving fixed support is consistent with the rural nature and the
nascent deployment of cable in many eligible carriers' study areas. We
expect the number of electing carriers' study areas deemed competitive
by the competitive market test will increase as competition grows and
cable companies expand their reach. This administratively simple
competitive market test ensures that all carriers are included in the
electing carriers' competitive market test and will have an opportunity
to be deregulated as competition develops.
3. Declining To Use the Results of the Price Cap Competitive Market
Test
88. Notwithstanding Petitioners' and some other commenters' request
that we use the results of the price cap competitive market test
adopted by the Commission in the BDS Order to determine where ex ante
pricing regulation should be removed from electing carriers' lower
capacity TDM end user channel termination services, we decline to do
so. In arguing that the Commission should use the BDS Order price cap
competitive market test for electing rate-of-return carriers, some
commenters claim ``the same marketplace analyses the Commission
undertook for price cap carriers apply equally to BDS provided by
model-based rate-of-return carriers.'' While using the results of the
existing competitive market test to determine whether an area served by
an electing carrier is competitive would be fast, no data in the record
support that approach. In fact, the result of the competitive market
test we adopt for electing carriers, which results in very few study
areas being deemed competitive, underscores our finding that
application of the price cap competitive market test results to
electing carriers--which would result in far more electing carriers'
study areas being deemed competitive--would not accurately measure
competition in the geographic areas served by rate-of-return carriers
receiving fixed support.
89. The BDS Order relied upon the largest information collection in
the history of the Commission to analyze and determine the competitive
nature of price cap carrier study areas. Even if a county contained
both price cap and rate-of-return study areas, the Commission's
analysis only included
[[Page 67110]]
the price cap study area. The Commission created the price cap
competitive market test after a thorough review of the 2015 Collection,
Form 477 data, and established the specific test metrics based upon an
informed knowledge of the level of competition that existed and was
necessary to protect consumers in the absence of regulation.
Petitioners, however, offer no data showing the extent of BDS
competition in areas served by rate-of-return carriers that receive
fixed support. Instead, they argue that the level of competition on a
county-by-county basis for price cap carriers' lower capacity TDM-based
BDS offerings is comparable to the level of competition for lower
capacity TDM-based BDS offerings of rate-of-return carriers that
receive fixed support. The principal support Petitioners offer for this
assertion is a study that purports to demonstrate that price cap rural
areas immediately proximate to certain A-CAM study areas exhibit
sufficiently similar characteristics that we should include A-CAM study
areas in the same competitive market test that we used for price cap
carriers. We find the Petitioners' study unpersuasive.
90. The study suffers from several methodological defects. First,
the study is not based on a representative sample of electing carriers'
study areas. Instead, it relies solely on Consolidated Communications'
rate-of-return study areas. We are doubtful, for example, that the
Consolidated study areas are a good proxy for the Alaska rate-of-return
carriers that are eligible to elect our new regulatory framework.
Second, two of the study's principal metrics (population and housing
density) are unlikely to be the critical drivers of competitive BDS
deployment.
91. Additionally, in some instances the study compares non-
urbanized price cap areas with areas served by rate-of-return carriers
that receive fixed support that include urbanized areas. These areas
are not comparable. At least some of the counties included in the
study's comparison were deemed non-competitive by the price cap
competitive market test. Inclusion in the price cap competitive market
test of A-CAM areas in these instances would have no effect on the
regulatory status of these study areas. The study does not directly
compare study areas with high cable presence with competitive counties
and study areas with low cable presence with non-competitive counties,
as would be expected if the study was trying to show similarities.
92. The study also compares the percentage of census blocks with
cable broadband availability between price cap and nearby A-CAM areas
and claims that, on average, ``the percentage of Census blocks in
Consolidated tracts with cable service (21%) is similar to the
surrounding rural price cap tracts (28%).'' But the study's use of
average percentages obscures wide variations in percentage cable
broadband deployment. For price cap study areas, cable broadband
deployment was found to be 3.88% to 68.68%. For A-CAM study areas,
broadband deployment in areas varied from 0.00% to 89.60%. The study
further attempts to compare price cap areas with nearby A-CAM areas by
claiming that the differences in the percentage of cable broadband
deployment between the two sets of areas are small, ``only 15
percentage points.'' This is not small.
93. The study also does not state whether it limited its analysis
of cable deployment in rate-of-return study areas to those deployments
offering a minimum of 10/1 Mbps. The study may have included
residential cable deployments at speeds lower than the threshold the
Commission established for the price cap competitive market test. Any
such deployments should not be included in a comparison of price cap
and nearby A-CAM areas.
94. We are also unable to rely on the conclusions in the
Petitioners' study since it is based on a misplaced reliance on
inaccuracies inherent in the structure of the price cap competitive
market test--inaccuracies the Commission acknowledged when it adopted
the competitive market test in the BDS Order. In the BDS Order, the
Commission conceded that its county-based competitive market test
unavoidably included a relatively small number of areas that would be
inappropriately regulated or inappropriately deregulated. It explained
that the only competitive market test that would be free of such
inaccuracies would be one that would be run at a building level--with
over a million buildings with BDS demand, an administratively
unworkable option. It adopted percentage thresholds for both prongs of
the competitive market test and employed certain statistical tools to
ensure those thresholds were set at levels that would minimize
inaccuracies. It further reasoned that competitive options would become
available for many of these areas in the short- to medium-term given
the dynamic nature of the BDS marketplace.
95. The Petitioners' study attempts to compare A-CAM areas to some
of the very price cap areas most likely to contain these inaccuracies
and to argue that these inaccuracies justify inclusion of rural A-CAM
areas in the price cap competitive market test. Extrapolating from the
characterization of peripheral parts of price cap study areas to A-CAM
areas is likely to exacerbate these inaccuracies. And unnecessarily so,
since the competitive market test we adopt offers a simple way of
estimating competition in A-CAM study areas. Further, these are areas
the study concedes typically lack even the most basic evidence of BDS
competition. Areas where there is little evidence of competition are
also likely areas where there is little to no demand for BDS.
96. Given these methodological and conceptual flaws, we conclude
that the Petitioners' study fails to establish the comparability of
price cap and nearby A-CAM areas or provide a reasonable basis on which
to include A-CAM areas in the price cap competitive market test. We
therefore decline to apply the results of the price cap competitive
market test to electing carriers' serving areas.
4. Updating Competitive Market Test Results
97. Consistent with the BDS Order competitive market test, we
eliminate ex ante pricing regulation of circuit-based end user channel
terminations at or below a DS3 level in study areas deemed competitive
by the electing carriers' competitive market test. We direct the Bureau
to release a Public Notice that lists the results of the competitive
market test, and to provide the information on the Commission's
website. We will re-run the electing carriers' competitive market test
every three years to assess whether any additional electing carriers'
study areas meet the 75% threshold. This will identify any additional
electing carriers' study areas that should be deemed competitive. We
believe a three-year timeframe balances the need to ensure the electing
carriers' competitive market test remains accurate and the Commission's
desire to avoid disrupting contracts and burdening carriers with overly
frequent updates. The sunk and irreversible cost of providing business
data services and deploying a network represents the biggest barrier to
entry for providers. Once the barrier is overcome, the marginal cost of
operating is low, so it is unlikely that competition will exit. Thus,
electing carriers' study areas deemed competitive will not be
reassessed.
98. To avoid confusion from both carriers and businesses stemming
from updates from the price cap competitive market test and the
electing carriers competitive market test, we direct the Wireline
Competition Bureau to re-run the three-year updates for both the BDS
Order price cap competitive market test,
[[Page 67111]]
and the electing carriers competitive market test concurrently. Thus,
the electing carriers' competitive market test will initially be re-run
in 2020, at the same time as the BDS Order price cap competitive market
test, to align the tests' timing. The re-running of these tests will
coincide with the initial running of the test for carriers electing to
convert to incentive regulation as of July 1, 2020. After that, both
tests will be re-run every three years. This approach will make it
easier for stakeholders to determine the regulatory status of price cap
and rate-of-return BDS providers since the results will be published
all at once and ease the burden on Commission resources. The Bureau
shall release a Public Notice that lists newly competitive counties
(for price cap areas) and study areas (for electing carriers' study
areas) and shall also provide this information on the Commission's
website. As with the BDS Order competitive market test, parties may
challenge the results of the electing carriers' competitive market test
by filing petitions for reconsideration or by seeking full Commission
review through an application for review.
5. Removal of Ex Ante Pricing Regulation of Electing Carriers' Lower
Capacity TDM End User Channel Termination Services
99. We remove ex ante pricing regulation from electing carriers'
lower capacity TDM end user channel termination services offered in
study areas that are deemed competitive by the electing carriers'
competitive market test. Such services are presumed to be subject to
sufficient competitive pressure that removing this layer of regulation
will not result in excessive rates. Removing this layer of regulation
will reduce unnecessary regulatory burdens and will enable these
carriers to contribute to BDS competition in their markets. Such
services in such areas will be relieved of ex ante pricing regulation
and detariffed in the same manner and with the same transition
provisions as we adopt today for electing carriers' packet-based and
higher capacity TDM BDS. As with packet-based and higher capacity TDM
BDS, we continue to maintain our oversight over these TDM services
pursuant to sections 201, 202, and 208 of the Act to ensure rates for
these services remain just and reasonable. Lower capacity TDM transport
and end user channel termination services in areas deemed
noncompetitive by the competitive market test will continue to be
subject to the incentive regulation and pricing flexibility we adopt
today.
D. Ending Ex Ante Pricing Regulation for Electing Carriers' Packet-
Based and Higher Capacity TDM BDS Offerings
100. We conclude that electing carriers' packet-based and higher
capacity TDM-based BDS offerings above a DS3 bandwidth level (which
includes both higher capacity TDM end user channel terminations and
higher capacity TDM transport) should not be subject to ex ante pricing
regulation and direct electing carriers to detariff these services
following a transition period. Our decision to end ex ante pricing
regulation for electing carriers' packet-based and higher capacity TDM
BDS offerings will facilitate competition for and deployment of these
packet-based and higher capacity TDM services and is consistent with
the Commission's statutory obligation to ensure that rates are just and
reasonable.
101. In the BDS Order, after reviewing an extensive record, the
Commission found that in price cap markets nationwide there was no
compelling evidence of incumbent LEC market power for packet-based and
higher capacity circuit-based BDS. Specifically, the record
demonstrated that demand for these services was increasing, prices were
declining, and competitive investment was growing significantly. The
Commission also determined that the price cap BDS market for packet-
based and higher capacity TDM-based offerings had the characteristics
of a bidding market such that even competitors that did not have pre-
existing facilities to serve a potential customer were nonetheless
capable and willing to bid on requests for proposals by customers,
particularly those with higher bandwidth needs.
102. The record in this proceeding lacks the comprehensive and
voluminous data collection available to the Commission in the price cap
BDS proceeding. But, we recognize that re-creating such a similarly
detailed data collection would have been more difficult for rate-of-
return carriers that receive fixed support, because they have vastly
fewer resources to produce such information and the benefits of such a
data collection would likely be far outweighed by its costs. Instead,
we draw parallels where we can from our conclusions in the BDS Order to
inform our analysis of the record in this proceeding.
103. In the BDS Order, the fact that the Commission could not find
compelling evidence to suggest market power in packet-based and higher
capacity TDM BDS in price cap markets suggests that the same
circumstances could exist in electing carriers' BDS markets. A variety
of companies are investing in next generation networks, not legacy
networks, to compete via different technologies, which is consistent
with a lack of market power. Additionally, demand for high speed BDS
exists nationwide. Customer requests for proposals (RFPs) are not
restricted to price cap areas but seek proposals for service wherever
they have demand. Thus, the characteristics of a bidding market that
exist in price cap areas are also likely to be present in areas served
by rate-of-return carriers that receive fixed support.
104. Relatedly, there is evidence that the deployment of fiber and
sales of packet-based BDS such as Ethernet continue to grow
substantially and pervasively. Analysts report that, for the first
time, fiber-connected commercial building penetration exceeded 50% in
2017--the availability of optical fiber connectivity to large and
medium size commercial buildings in the U.S. increased from 49.6% in
2016 to 54.8% in 2017. In 2018, 98% of our nation's elementary and
secondary school districts are served by fiber optic or other high
speed connections. An analyst's equipment revenue forecast for 2017 to
2022 projects that Ethernet access and aggregation will grow 9%
annually. The record in this proceeding shows that these growth trends
are also apparent in A-CAM carriers' served areas. For example, TDS
Telecom, Great Plains, and Consolidated report a four-year average
annual growth rate in Ethernet sales from December 2014 to 2017 of
10.7%, 15.4%, and 38.3%, respectively. Over the same periods, these
carriers report declines in legacy BDS in study areas that were similar
to declines in legacy BDS in price cap areas. At the same time,
consistent with the Commission's findings in the BDS Order, analysts
report actual and forecasted growth in cable revenues, deployment and
market share for small to national enterprise customers that are
significantly contributing to overall growth and competition in the BDS
market.
105. There are other reasons to believe market power for packet-
based and higher capacity TDM business data services is not present in
areas served by rate-of-return carriers that receive fixed support. The
record shows that large customers have significant bargaining leverage
over relatively smaller rate-of-return carriers that receive fixed
support, limiting what the carriers may negotiate when bidding on
contracts. For example, ex ante pricing regulation is unnecessary to
protect large and powerful entities, such as wireless
[[Page 67112]]
carriers, that purchase large quantities of BDS.
106. The Commission has repeatedly emphasized its preference for
relying on competition instead of regulation. We seek to minimize the
burdens of regulation while ensuring that rates and practices remain
just and reasonable. The Commission previously identified packet-based
services as the ``future of business data services'' that are also
``readily scalable.'' While legacy TDM BDS is declining, carriers,
including rate-of-return carriers that receive fixed support, are
generally investing aggressively to deploy high speed networks in their
study areas. The record shows growing demand for packet-based and
higher capacity TDM BDS consistent with the Commission's findings in
the BDS Order, and we find the record persuasive.
107. Removing ex ante pricing regulation for packet-based and
higher capacity TDM services, will also encourage innovation. As the
Commission has previously found, the potential unintended costs of
regulation are far greater for new services. The Commission has
concluded that ex ante pricing regulation for these services should not
be imposed even with ``insufficiently robust competition'' because it
would be difficult to administer such complex regulations. We are
keenly aware of the risk that heavy-handed regulation could discourage
competitive investment which would have long-term negative consequences
on competitive deployment over time.
108. These considerations also apply to the study areas of rate-of-
return carriers that receive fixed support. Innovation does not stop at
the borders of a price cap carrier's study areas. The record shows that
all providers are accelerating their deployment of next generation
packet-based services in response to customer demand. We find that the
sensitivity of new and growing services to imprecise regulation,
particularly rate regulation, is a factor in areas served by rate-of-
return carriers receiving fixed support as well as areas served by
price cap carriers. For that reason, consistent with our decision in
the BDS Order, we find that the costs and potential risks of ex ante
pricing regulation for packet-based and higher capacity TDM business
data services exceed the benefits and we therefore eliminate such
regulation. This result provides regulatory parity between electing
carriers and price cap carriers in their provision of packet-based and
higher capacity TDM business data services which will benefit
consumers.
109. We eliminate ex ante pricing regulation on the provision of
these services by electing carriers to hasten deployment of advanced
services and because competition and the size of purchasers of these
services is sufficient to protect consumers. We affirm, however, that
the Commission retains authority under sections 201, 202, and 208 of
the Act to ensure that packet-based and higher capacity TDM BDS rates
and practices are just, reasonable, and not unreasonably
discriminatory. The availability of the protections of sections 201 and
202, and the importance of the formal fast-track complaint process of
section 208, will provide sufficient protection against unreasonable
rates and practices in this increasingly competitive market.
E. Implementation Issues
110. We take a series of additional steps to ensure electing
carriers will be able fully to implement the BDS regulatory framework
we adopt today, including adopting deadlines for implementing incentive
regulation, forbearing from cost assignment and jurisdictional
separations rules, forbearing from Sec. 54.1305 reporting
requirements, forbearing from section 203 tariffing requirements,
allowing electing carriers to elect to use GAAP accounting instead of
part 32 accounting, and adopting certain transitional timeframes to
facilitate the detariffing of electing carriers' packet-based and
higher capacity TDM offerings.
1. Effective Date of Elections
111. We adopt the following requirements to implement voluntary
incentive regulation for electing carriers. We adopt the proposal in
the NPRM to make incentive regulation for electing carriers effective
as of July 1, 2019 and add a second election date option for carriers
that will be effective July 1, 2020. We agree with Petitioners that a
January 1, 2019 effective date would be the least burdensome for
carriers because cost studies are performed on a calendar year basis
and ``would benefit customers and competition alike.'' However, a
January 1, 2019 effective date is not practicable because the rules
adopted in this Order contain new or modified information collection
requirements triggering Paperwork Reduction Act review by the Office of
Management and Budget (OMB), a process which takes approximately five
months to complete. A January 1, 2019 effective date would also provide
insufficient time for electing carriers in the traffic-sensitive NECA
pool to remove their BDS offerings from the pool. Our rules require
that annual access charge tariff filings be filed with a scheduled
effective date of July 1. As such, a July 1 effective date is
consistent with current tariffing procedures and will simplify the
implementation of the changes adopted in this Order.
112. Similarly, we adopt July 1 as the effective date for any
future election. July 1 is the most efficient effective date because
allowing carriers accepting future offers of A-CAM support to set their
initial rates on another date would add cost and complexity to the
process. Petitioners suggest using a January 1 effective date but doing
so would require an electing carrier to make an additional tariff
filing beyond the required July 1 annual filing. NECA, and the
Commission, would have to undertake their associated review of the
tariff, and NECA would be required to conduct its mid-year cost studies
for the remaining pool members, calculate support for existing members,
reband, and undertake other steps it would not do otherwise.
Additionally, a January 1 effective date would be based on the previous
year's cost study. Relying on year-old data would undermine the
validity of the tariff filings. It is possible that an electing carrier
could prepare a cost study for only a portion of the current year and
multiply the results of the study to estimate a year's data, but that
approach creates additional burdens for carriers, complicates NECA's
implementation, and would still not represent a fully accurate picture
of the carrier's costs and demand. When considered together, we find
that using July 1 as a deadline for setting initial rates in any future
A-CAM offer is the most efficient and feasible approach.
113. Electing carriers currently in the NECA pool are required to
notify NECA by March 1, 2019 that they will not participate in the
upcoming NECA traffic-sensitive tariff for their BDS offerings
consistent with Sec. 69.3 of our rules. Similarly, NECA pool carriers
that elect to convert to incentive regulation effective July 1, 2020,
must notify NECA that they will not participate in the NECA traffic-
sensitive pool for BDS offerings by March 1, 2020. NECA pool carriers
that accept future offers of A-CAM support and elect the incentive
regulation framework we adopt today or otherwise transition away from
legacy support mechanisms must notify NECA by March 1 of their election
year consistent with Sec. 69.3. The Commission proposed requiring
electing carriers to provide the Bureau with 120 days' notice of their
election to facilitate implementation of the revised tariffs but we now
agree with Petitioners that
[[Page 67113]]
opposed granting so much advanced notice. Accordingly, we require
electing carriers electing to convert to incentive regulation effective
July 1, 2019 to provide the Bureau with notice of their election by May
1, 2019. Carriers that elect our second incentive regulation option
date, effective July 1, 2020, must notify the Bureau by May 1, 2020.
Carriers that accept future offers of A-CAM support and carriers that
otherwise transition away from legacy support mechanisms must provide
notice of their election or transition to the Bureau by May 1 of the
year of election or transition. Electing carriers that choose to update
their separations category relationships pursuant to this Order shall
include information to that effect in these notices to NECA and the
Bureau.
2. Implementing Forbearance
114. As part of implementing our new regulatory framework for
electing carriers' BDS, we grant forbearance from certain existing
Commission rules and statutory requirements, including our tariffing
obligations for electing carriers' packet-based and higher capacity
(i.e., above a DS3 bandwidth level) TDM business data services and
lower capacity TDM end user channel termination services in study areas
deemed competitive; our Cost Assignment Rules; and our Sec. 54.1305
reporting requirements, for electing carriers' lower capacity (i.e., at
or below a DS3 bandwidth level) TDM transport and end user channel
termination services. Forbearance will be effective July 1, 2019 for
carriers electing incentive regulation of their business data services
as of July 1, 2019, and July 1, 2020 for carrier's electing incentive
regulation as of July 1, 2020. Section 10 of the Act requires that the
Commission forbear from applying any provision of the Act, or any of
the Commission's regulations, if the Commission determines that: (1)
Enforcement of the provision or regulation is not necessary to ensure
that a telecommunications carrier's ``charges, practices,
classifications or regulations'' are ``just and reasonable and are not
unjustly or unreasonably discriminatory,'' (2) enforcement of the
provision or regulation is ``not necessary for the protection of
consumers,'' and (3) forbearance is consistent with the public
interest. In making the public interest determination, the Commission
must also consider, pursuant to section 10(b), ``whether forbearance
from enforcing the provision or regulation will promote competitive
market conditions.'' We find that granting forbearance in these
instances will meet the statutory forbearance requirements and will
facilitate electing carriers' transition to incentive regulation,
putting them on a footing similar to that of price cap carriers in
their provision of BDS.
a. Forbearance from Tariffing Requirements for Packet-Based and Higher
Capacity TDM Services and Lower Capacity TDM End User Channel
Terminations in Study Areas Deemed Competitive
115. In order to effectuate our light-touch regulatory framework
for packet-based and higher capacity TDM business data services above
the DS3 bandwidth level, we grant forbearance, pursuant to section 10
of the Act, from section 203 tariffing requirements for these services
offered by electing carriers. In addition, we grant forbearance for
lower capacity TDM end user channel terminations offered in electing
carriers' study areas deemed competitive by the competitive market
test. Forbearance from section 203 tariffing obligations is warranted
under section 10 of the Act, is consistent with our finding that
electing carriers lack market power in packet-based and higher capacity
TDM business data services, and end user channel terminations in study
areas deemed competitive by the competitive market test, and will
enhance competition and deployment of these next generation services.
116. Forbearance from section 203 tariffing requirements for
packet-based and higher capacity TDM BDS offerings above the DS3
bandwidth level, and for lower capacity TDM end user channel
terminations in study areas deemed competitive by the competitive
market test, satisfies all three prongs of the forbearance analysis.
First, pursuant to section 10(a)(1), we conclude in the context of
growing demand for high speed services detariffing these services will
promote competitive market conditions, which will result in lower
prices and better services, thus ensuring that electing carriers'
relevant charges, practices, classifications, and regulations are just
and reasonable and not unreasonably discriminatory. Similarly, the
existence of demonstrated competition for end user channel terminations
in markets deemed competitive will restrain anticompetitive behavior,
lower prices, increase innovation, and protect consumers from charges,
practices, classifications, and regulations that are not just and
reasonable and unreasonably discriminatory. Competition will serve to
limit electing carriers' behavior. Absent forbearance, as commenters
argue, Commission regulation could have the inverse effect and harm
competition and network deployment.
117. We also conclude that, pursuant to section 10(a)(2),
enforcement of our tariffing requirements for these services is ``not
necessary for the protection of consumers.'' Indeed, by encouraging
competition, granting forbearance from tariffing of these services will
benefit consumers by increasing deployment and lowering cost.
Competition among carriers and the roll-out of next generation packet-
based and higher capacity TDM circuit-based BDS will lower prices and
provide new services. In study areas deemed competitive, competition
will also protect consumers. The Commission has previously found that
tariffs were originally required to protect consumers but they are
unnecessary if a provider faces competitive pressures. If an electing
carrier harms a consumer the consumer can switch to other competitors
present in the study area. This threat protects consumers. Of course,
in the event that there is risk of consumer harm, sections 201, 202,
and 208 remain applicable to enforce the Commission's rules and protect
consumers' welfare. Based on competition in the market and our
statutory mandate as a backstop, we find that section 203 is not
necessary to protect consumers in electing carriers' packet-based and
higher capacity TDM markets, and for lower capacity TDM end user
channel termination in study areas deemed competitive by the electing
carriers' competitive market test.
118. Third, we conclude that forbearance from these statutory and
regulatory requirements is in the public interest. Forbearance from the
tariffing requirement for these packet-based and higher capacity TDM
services and for lower capacity TDM end user channel terminations in
markets deemed competitive will promote competition, reduce compliance
costs, increase investment and innovation, and facilitate the
technology transitions. We therefore find that application of section
203 is not necessary under sections 10(a)(1) and 10(a)(2), and is in
the public interest, consistent with sections 10(a)(3) and 10(b).
b. Cost Assignment Rules Forbearance
119. In light of our decision to relieve electing carriers of the
obligation to conduct cost studies, we grant electing carriers
forbearance, pursuant to section 10 of the Act, from the Commission's
Cost Assignment Rules for their BDS services, although we grant
forbearance for their lower capacity (i.e., at or below
[[Page 67114]]
a DS3 bandwidth level) TDM transport and end user channel termination
services after they have set initial rates for those offerings.
Additionally, electing carriers that participate in the NECA pool must
conduct cost studies for the calendar year prior to their election and
the first half of the year of their election to comply with their pool
settlement requirements.
120. Background. The Cost Assignment Rules generally require
carriers to assign costs to build and maintain the network and revenues
from services provided to specific categories. Categories include
nonregulated or regulated service, the intrastate or interstate
jurisdiction, and specific access services, such as local switching or
common line. The Cost Assignment Rules also govern the accounting
treatment of transactions between a carrier and its affiliate, such as
the sale or transfer of assets between regulated and nonregulated
affiliates. In addition, the rules include certain reporting
requirements, which depend on the availability of data produced by the
Cost Assignment Rules.
121. As part of the regulatory accounting process, carriers first
record their costs, including investments and expenses, into various
accounts in accordance with the Uniform System of Accounts (USOA)
prescribed by part 32 of the Commission's rules. Next, using the Cost
Assignment Rules in part 64, carriers directly assign, or allocate if
direct assignment is not possible, the costs and revenues associated
with their regulated and nonregulated activities. After costs and
revenues are divided between those that are regulated and nonregulated,
interstate and intrastate costs and revenues are separated as provided
in part 36. Federal and state regulatory jurisdictions apply their own
ratemaking processes to the amounts assigned to each jurisdiction.
Finally, the access charge rules in part 69 require carriers to
separate regulated interstate costs into interexchange costs and access
costs, and then apportion the latter among access categories or
elements.
122. The Commission adopted the Cost Assignment Rules to help
ensure that carriers charge just and reasonable rates for the services
they provide. The Commission adopted the Cost Assignment Rules prior to
1991 when all incumbent LECs were subject to rate-of-return regulation,
so that it could set rates that allowed carriers to recover their costs
and earn a specific return on their regulated investment. Subsequently,
the Commission moved away from rate-of-return regulation for the larger
incumbent LECs. In its place, it adopted price cap regulation, a form
of incentive regulation that seeks to ``harness the profit-making
incentives common to all businesses to produce a set of outcomes that
advance the public interest goals of just, reasonable, and
nondiscriminatory rates, as well as a communications system that offers
innovative, high quality services.''
123. In 2008, the Commission granted AT&T conditional forbearance
from the Cost Assignment Rules. The Commission conditioned the
forbearance on, among other things, requiring AT&T to retain part 32
Uniform System of Accounts data and submit a compliance plan describing
in detail how it would fulfill its statutory and regulatory
requirements. The Commission granted similar conditional forbearance
from the Cost Assignment Rules to Verizon and Qwest. Subsequently,
Qwest, Verizon, and AT&T obtained conditional forbearance from certain
financial reporting requirements that relied on the Cost Assignment
Rules. In 2013, the Commission extended the conditional forbearance
granted the three carriers to all price cap carriers.
124. In the Part 32 Order, 82 FR 20833, May 4, 2017, the Commission
terminated the conditions that the Commission placed on a variety of
carriers granted forbearance from our Cost Assignment Rules. The
Commission noted that forbearance was expressly premised on the
continued availability of part 32 accounting data and the filing of
compliance plans consistent with that condition. The Commission
determined that continuing to maintain these costly requirements on the
speculation that at some point the Commission might do something with
them failed any cost-benefit analysis.
125. Discussion. We find that applying the Cost Assignment Rules to
electing carriers is no longer necessary to ensure that charges and
practices are just, reasonable, and not unjustly or unreasonably
discriminatory; to protect consumers; or to protect the public
interest. Much of the reasoning in the Commission's earlier decisions
to grant price cap LECs forbearance from the Cost Assignment Rules
applies equally to rate-of-return carriers receiving fixed support that
elect incentive regulation. With respect to ensuring charges,
practices, classifications, and regulations are just and reasonable and
not unjustly or unreasonably discriminatory, as discussed above, the
Cost Assignment Rules were developed when the incumbent LECs'
interstate rates and many of their intrastate rates were set under
rate-based, cost-of-service regulation. Because the incentive
regulation we adopt severs for BDS the direct link between regulated
costs and prices just as price cap regulation did, a carrier is not
able automatically to recoup misallocated nonregulated costs by raising
BDS rates, thus reducing incentives to shift nonregulated costs to
regulated services. To the extent incentives remain, we find our
positive experience with the waivers of the all-or-nothing rule
provides confidence that the additional costs of maintaining the Cost
Assignment Rules outweighs any possible benefit of maintaining them.
There is no reason to impose on electing carriers cost assignment
requirements that were ``designed to parallel the level of detail in
the cost-of-service calculations that LECs performed to develop their
rates for interstate access services.'' Moreover, if the need arises
for cost data from electing carriers, we find there are less costly
ways to meet that need.
126. With respect to the second prong of the forbearance test,
protecting consumers, the Commission adopted the Cost Assignment Rules
in part to help protect consumers from improper cross-subsidization of
competitive services provided on an integrated basis with
noncompetitive services by dominant providers with individual market
power. Because the rates for regulated services and the determination
of the level of universal service support are no longer tied to
accounting costs, electing carriers will have no incentive to shift
costs between regulated and nonregulated services, or to services
receiving universal service support, thus the consumer protection
issues that animate the Cost Assignment Rules are not relevant for
electing carriers.
127. We also find that forbearing from the Cost Assignment Rules
for electing carriers is in the public interest. Because neither rates
nor universal service support will be cost-based for electing carriers,
relieving electing carriers of the expense of compliance with the Cost
Assignment Rules will allow electing carriers to offer more competitive
rates and more innovative service, thus furthering the public interest.
128. Finally, section 10(b) requires us to consider, as part of our
analysis of the public interest prong, whether forbearance will promote
competitive market conditions. We agree with Petitioners, TDS Telecom
and other commenters that contend that forbearance will enhance
competition. Eliminating unnecessary regulation will generally reduce
electing carriers' costs and, in turn, benefit consumers through lower
rates and/or more vibrant
[[Page 67115]]
competitive offerings. Because other providers of similar services are
not subject to the rules, it also promotes competition by providing a
more level playing field. Moreover, as noted above, we find that
sufficient protections remain in place to prevent anti-competitive
cross-subsidization.
129. We note that there still may be instances in which an electing
carrier seeks some other type of relief from the Commission that
requires supporting cost assignment data. In such instances, the burden
is on the carrier to retain data sufficient to make the required
showing to the Commission in support of such a carrier-initiated
request.
130. As part of our forbearance from the Cost Assignment Rules, we
also forbear from the NECA data reporting requirement in Sec. 54.1305
of our rules and, by extension, from the related requirement to update
information shared with NECA. Under the Commission's rules, incumbent
LECs are required to report unseparated loop cost data to NECA
annually. Price cap carriers and their affiliates have been exempt from
this obligation since the Commission adopted the USF/ICC Transformation
Order and various price cap cost assignment forbearance orders. This
reporting requirement depends on the availability of data produced by
the Cost Assignment Rules. As part of the forbearance adopted in this
Order, we cease to require data that would otherwise be reported as
part of a cost study. Retaining this obligation is thus inconsistent
with our grant of forbearance and is inconsistent with past price cap
carrier forbearance grants. Retaining this obligation would also
eliminate one of the core incentives for rate-of-return carriers to
elect incentive regulation--cost savings from the elimination of the
obligation to undertake cost studies.
131. Granting forbearance from NECA reporting requirements
satisfies all three prongs of the forbearance analysis. The NECA data
collection requirement is not necessary to ensure that carrier charges
and practices are just and reasonable, as evidenced by the fact that
price cap carriers have been operating without NECA reporting for
nearly six years without issue. While no longer including electing
carriers' data in the calculation of the national average cost per loop
will affect that calculation, we do not think that any impact it may
have outweighs the benefits of removing these reporting obligations.
Since the very goal of incentive regulation is to disconnect cost and
rates to promote competition in the marketplace, reporting cost data to
NECA is also unnecessary to protect consumers. Additionally, because
forbearance from enforcing these rules is necessary to obtain the
benefit of reducing unnecessary regulatory compliance costs this Order
seeks, forbearance is consistent with the public interest. Retaining
the data collection and reporting requirements of Sec. Sec. 54.1305
and 54.1306 would force electing carriers to continue to perform annual
cost studies and would thus eliminate one of the chief sources of cost
savings of this Order. Forbearing from these requirements will promote
competition by allowing these resources to be redirected to increase
network investment and to accelerate the technology transition from
legacy circuit-based services to packet-based services such as
Ethernet.
3. GAAP Accounting
132. We allow electing carriers the option of using generally
accepted accounting principles (GAAP) for keeping their accounts. The
only commenters that oppose allowing electing carriers to use GAAP
accounting incorrectly argue that for electing carriers part 32, cost
studies and other protections are necessary because ``these electing
carriers would continue to have certain of their interstate services
under rate-of-return.'' In fact, as explained by Petitioners, all of
the interstate telecommunications services offered by electing carriers
will either be (1) subject to incentive regulation, (2) not subject to
ex ante pricing regulation, or (3) capped and transitioning downward by
the terms of the rate-of-return intercarrier compensation rules. Thus,
there is no significant reason to continue to maintain burdensome part
32 accounting for electing carriers.
133. The Commission recently revised its part 32 accounting rules
to allow price cap LECs to elect to use GAAP in recording and reporting
their financial data, subject to two targeted accounting requirements.
We subject electing carriers that choose to use GAAP accounting to the
same data provisioning requirements as price cap carriers, including
the requirements relating to the calculation of pole attachment rates.
Electing carriers may either (a) calculate an Implementation Rate
Difference between the attachment rates calculated by the carrier under
the Uniform System of Accounts (USOA) and under GAAP as of the last
full year preceding the carrier's initial opting-out of part 32 USOA
accounting requirements; or (b) comply with GAAP accounting for all
purposes other than those associated with setting pole attachment rates
while continuing to use the part 32 accounts and procedures necessary
to establish and evaluate pole attachment rates. Electing carriers must
adjust their annually computed GAAP-based rates by the Implementation
Rate Difference for a period of 12 years after the election. This will
free electing carriers from having to maintain two sets of books: one
for financial reporting purposes consistent with GAAP and one for
regulatory reporting purposes consistent with the accounting
requirements of part 32.
4. Transitions
134. Consistent with our actions in the BDS Order, our detariffing
actions in this Order for electing carriers' study areas will be
mandatory after a transition that will provide electing carriers
sufficient time to adapt their business data services operations to a
detariffing regime.
135. The transition period will begin on the date incentive
regulation becomes effective for electing carriers, either July 1, 2019
or July 1, 2020, and will end thirty-six (36) months thereafter, a
period that we find sufficient for electing carriers to adapt to a
detariffing regime. In addition, for six (6) months following the date
incentive regulation becomes effective, we require electing carriers to
freeze the tariffed rates for their business data services that are no
longer subject to ex ante pricing regulation, including lower speed TDM
end user channel terminations in newly deregulated study areas,
provided those services remain tariffed. These transition mechanisms
will ensure that small businesses and other purchasers have time to
adjust to the new regulatory framework we adopt.
136. Similarly, carriers electing incentive regulation in
connection with a subsequent offer of A-CAM support, or carriers that
the Commission otherwise transitions away from legacy support
mechanisms must detariff the relevant business data services within
thirty-six (36) months of the date on which their incentive-based rates
take effect or their transition away from legacy support mechanisms
becomes effective. Further, for six (6) months following such dates,
such carriers will be required to freeze their tariffed rates for BDS
that are no longer subject to ex ante pricing regulation, provided
those rates remain tariffed.
137. Tariffing for these services will be permissive during the
transition--we will accept new tariffs and revisions to existing
tariffs for the affected services during this time period. Electing
carriers may also detariff during the transition. Apart from the rate
freeze noted above, carriers will no longer be required to
[[Page 67116]]
comply with ex ante pricing regulation for these services. Once the
rules adopted in this Order are effective, carriers that wish to
continue filing tariffs under the permissive detariffing regime are
free to modify such tariffs to reflect the new regulatory structure
outlined in this Order for the affected services. This will allow
carriers to be more competitive and introduce new business data
services as they adapt to detariffing.
138. Electing carriers may remove the relevant portions of their
tariffs for the affected services at any time during the transition,
and the rate freeze does not apply to services that are no longer
tariffed. Electing carriers may not file or maintain any interstate
tariffs for affected business data services once the transition ends.
This will prevent electing carriers from obtaining ``deemed lawful''
status for tariff filings that are not accompanied by cost support and
invoking the filed-rate doctrine in contractual disputes with
customers. Business data service providers will also be prevented from
picking and choosing when they are able to invoke the protections of
tariffs.
139. We do not intend our actions to disturb existing contractual
or other long-term arrangements--a contract tariff remains a contract
even if it is no longer tariffed. As we stated in the BDS Order,
contract tariffs, term and volume discount plans, and individual
circuit plans do not become void upon detariffing. All carriers are to
act in good faith to develop solutions to ensure rates remain just and
reasonable.
III. Other Rule Changes
140. We adopt several other rule changes which can be found set out
below. These rule changes include changes arising from this Order as
well as corrections to inaccuracies in our current rules. Thus, we
change (1) the cross reference to Sec. 61.3(aa) in Sec. 51.903(g) to
Sec. 61.3(bb), (2) the cross reference to Sec. 61.3(ee) in Sec.
61.41(d) to Sec. 61.3(ff), (3) the cross reference Sec. 61.3(x) in
Sec. 69.114 to Sec. 61.3(ff), and (4) the cross reference to Sec.
69.801(g) in Sec. 69.805(a) to Sec. 69.801(h). These cross references
have been rendered inaccurate because of changes in the definitions
contained in Sec. 61.3.
IV. Final Regulatory Flexibility Analysis
141. As required by the Regulatory by the Regulatory Flexibility
Act of 1980, as amended (RFA) an Initial Regulatory Flexibility
Analysis (IRFA) was incorporated into the Notice of Proposed Rulemaking
(NPRM) for the rate-of-return business data services (BDS) proceeding.
The Commission sought written public comment on the proposals in the
NPRM, including comment on the IRFA. The Commission received no
comments on the IRFA. Because the Commission amends its rules in this
Report and Order, the Commission has included this Final Regulatory
Flexibility Analysis (FRFA). This present FRFA conforms to the RFA.
A. Need for, and Objectives of, the Rules
142. In the NPRM, the Commission proposed to adopt a form of
incentive regulation for the provision of business data services by
rate-of-return carriers receiving fixed universal service support,
conduct a market analysis to evaluate the characteristics of BDS
markets served by rate-of-return carriers receiving fixed support, and
adopt a new lighter touch regulatory framework for these carriers' BDS
that in most respects parallels the framework recently adopted for
price cap carriers in the BDS Order. This Order provides a new
framework for BDS offered by rate-of-return carriers that receive fixed
support that minimizes unnecessary regulatory burdens on certain rate-
of-return carriers and allows market forces to foster appropriate
incentives for these carriers to be efficient, to innovate and to
compete.
143. In this Order, the Commission takes the next step in a series
of steps to encourage carriers to move from rate-of-return to incentive
regulation, and to remove ex ante pricing regulation where competitive
conditions justify doing so. This Order focuses on allowing rate-of-
return carriers that currently receive fixed high-cost universal
service support to voluntarily elect to transition out of rate-of-
return regulation for their BDS offerings. In so doing, the Commission
amends its rules to allow such carriers to move their lower capacity
time division multiplexing (TDM) circuit-based transport and end user
channel termination offerings to incentive regulation while providing a
path for those carriers that elect our new framework (electing
carriers) to demonstrate that their lower capacity circuit-based end
user channel termination offerings are competitive, and therefore
should not be subject to ex ante pricing regulation. We also remove ex
ante pricing regulation from electing carriers' higher capacity
circuit-based and their packet-based BDS offerings.
144. Allowing rate-of-return carriers that receive fixed support to
move their BDS offerings away from rate-of-return regulation will help
drive competition for BDS offerings in the communities served by those
carriers. It will also reduce unnecessary regulatory burdens faced by
electing carriers. They will no longer be required to provide cost-
based justification for their BDS rates and will therefore no longer
need to conduct annual cost studies to justify those rates. They will
also no longer be required to file tariffs for their packed-based and
higher capacity TDM-based end user channel terminations offerings in
areas deemed competitive. The regulatory burdens on electing carriers,
most of which are small entities, will be vastly reduced.
145. We take these steps while affirming our core statutory
obligations pursuant to sections 201, 202, and 208 of the
Communications Act to ensure that the rates and practices of these
carriers' BDS remain just, reasonable and not unreasonably
discriminatory. Collectively, these actions will streamline regulation,
and spur entry, investment, innovation, and competition in the affected
BDS markets to the benefit of businesses and other institutional users
that rely on these services.
B. Summary of Significant Issues Raised by Public Comments in Response
to the IRFA
146. The Commission did not receive comments specifically
addressing the rules and policies proposed in the IRFA.
C. Response to Comments by the Chief Counsel for Advocacy of the Small
Business Administration
147. The Chief Counsel did not file any comments in response to
this proceeding.
D. Description and Estimate of the Number of Small Entities to Which
the Rules Will Apply
148. The RFA directs agencies to provide a description of, and
where feasible, an estimate of the number of small entities that may be
affected by the proposed rules, if adopted. The RFA generally defines
the term ``small entity'' as having the same meaning as the terms
``small business,'' ``small organization,'' and ``small governmental
jurisdiction.'' In addition, the term ``small business'' has the same
meaning as the term ``small-business concern'' under the Small Business
Act. A small-business concern'' is one which: (1) Is independently
owned and operated; (2) is not dominant in its field of operation; and
(3) satisfies any additional criteria established by the Small Business
Administration (SBA).
1. Total Small Entities
149. Our proposed action, if implemented, may, over time, affect
[[Page 67117]]
small entities that are not easily categorized at present. We therefore
describe here, at the outset, three comprehensive, statutory small
entity size standards. First, as of 2013, the SBA estimates there are
an estimated 28.8 million small businesses nationwide--comprising some
99.9% of all businesses. In addition, a ``small organization'' is
generally ``any not-for-profit enterprise which is independently owned
and operated and is not dominant in its field.'' Nationwide, as of
2007, there were approximately 1,621,315 small organizations. Finally,
the term ``small governmental jurisdiction'' is defined generally as
``governments of cities, towns, townships, villages, school districts,
or special districts, with a population of less than fifty thousand.''
Census Bureau data for 2012 indicate that there were 90,056 local
governmental jurisdictions in the United States. We estimate that, of
this total, as many as 89,195 entities may qualify as ``small
governmental jurisdictions.'' Thus, we estimate that most governmental
jurisdictions are small.
2. Broadband internet Access Service Providers
150. internet Service Providers (Broadband). Broadband internet
service providers include wired (e.g., cable, DSL) and VoIP service
providers using their own operated wired telecommunications
infrastructure fall in the category of Wired Telecommunication
Carriers. Wired Telecommunications Carriers are comprised of
establishments primarily engaged in operating and/or providing access
to transmission facilities and infrastructure that they own and/or
lease for the transmission of voice, data, text, sound, and video using
wired telecommunications networks. Transmission facilities may be based
on a single technology or a combination of technologies. The SBA size
standard for this category classifies a business as small if it has
1,500 or fewer employees. U.S. Census data for 2012 show that there
were 3,117 firms that operated that year. Of this total, 3,083 operated
with fewer than 1,000 employees. Consequently, under this size standard
the majority of firms in this industry can be considered small.
3. Wireline Providers
151. Wired Telecommunications Carriers. The U.S. Census Bureau
defines this industry as ``establishments primarily engaged in
operating and/or providing access to transmission facilities and
infrastructure that they own and/or lease for the transmission of
voice, data, text, sound, and video using wired communications
networks. Transmission facilities may be based on a single technology
or a combination of technologies. Establishments in this industry use
the wired telecommunications network facilities that they operate to
provide a variety of services, such as wired telephony services,
including VoIP services, wired (cable) audio and video programming
distribution, and wired broadband internet services. By exception,
establishments providing satellite television distribution services
using facilities and infrastructure that they operate are included in
this industry.'' The SBA has developed a small business size standard
for Wired Telecommunications Carriers, which consists of all such
companies having 1,500 or fewer employees. Census data for 2012 show
that there were 3,117 firms that operated that year. Of this total,
3,083 operated with fewer than 1,000 employees. Thus, under this size
standard, the majority of firms in this industry can be considered
small.
152. Incumbent Local Exchange Carriers (Incumbent LECs). Neither
the Commission nor the SBA has developed a small business size standard
specifically for incumbent LEC services. The closest applicable size
standard under SBA rules is for the category Wired Telecommunications
Carriers as defined above. Under that size standard, such a business is
small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees. According to Commission data,
3,117 firms operated in that year. Of this total, 3,083 operated with
fewer than 1,000 employees. Consequently, the Commission estimates that
most providers of incumbent local exchange service are small businesses
that may be affected by the rules and policies adopted. A total of
1,307 firms reported that they were incumbent local exchange service
providers. Of this total, an estimated 1,006 have 1,500 or fewer
employees.
153. Competitive Local Exchange Carriers (Competitive LECs),
Competitive Access Providers (CAPs), Shared-Tenant Service Providers,
and Other Local Service Providers. Neither the Commission nor the SBA
has developed a small business size standard specifically for these
service providers. The appropriate NAICS Code category is Wired
Telecommunications Carriers, as defined above. Under that size
standard, such a business is small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees.
U.S. Census data for 2012 indicate that 3,117 firms operated during
that year. Of that number, 3,083 operated with fewer than 1,000
employees. Based on this data, the Commission concludes that the
majority of Competitive LECS, CAPs, Shared-Tenant Service Providers,
and Other Local Service Providers, are small entities. According to
Commission data, 1,442 carriers reported that they were engaged in the
provision of either competitive local exchange services or competitive
access provider services. Of these 1,442 carriers, an estimated 1,256
have 1,500 or fewer employees. In addition, 17 carriers have reported
that they are Shared-Tenant Service Providers, and all 17 are estimated
to have 1,500 or fewer employees. Also, 72 carriers have reported that
they are Other Local Service Providers. Of this total, 70 have 1,500 or
fewer employees. Consequently, based on internally researched FCC data,
the Commission estimates that most providers of competitive local
exchange service, competitive access providers, Shared-Tenant Service
Providers, and Other Local Service Providers are small entities.
154. We have included small incumbent LECs in this present RFA
analysis. As noted above, a ``small business'' under the RFA is one
that, inter alia, meets the pertinent small business size standard
(e.g., a telephone communications business having 1,500 or fewer
employees), and ``is not dominant in its field of operation.'' The
SBA's Office of Advocacy contends that, for RFA purposes, small
incumbent LECs are not dominant in their field of operation because any
such dominance is not ``national'' in scope. We have therefore included
small incumbent LECs in this RFA analysis, although we emphasize that
this RFA action has no effect on Commission analyses and determinations
in other, non-RFA contexts.
155. Interexchange Carriers (IXCs). Neither the Commission nor the
SBA has developed a definition for Interexchange Carriers. The closest
NAICS Code category is Wired Telecommunications Carriers as defined
above. The applicable size standard under SBA rules is that such a
business is small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees. U.S. Census data
for 2012 indicates that 3,117 firms operated during that year. Of that
number, 3,083 operated with fewer than 1,000 employees. According to
internally developed Commission data, 359 companies reported that their
primary telecommunications service activity was the provision of
interexchange services. Of this total, an estimated 317 have 1,500 or
fewer employees. Consequently, the Commission estimates that the
majority of IXCs are small entities that may be affected by our rules.
[[Page 67118]]
156. Local Resellers. The SBA has developed a small business size
standard for the category of Telecommunications Resellers. The
Telecommunications Resellers industry comprises establishments engaged
in purchasing access and network capacity from owners and operators of
telecommunications networks and reselling wired and wireless
telecommunications services (except satellite) to businesses and
households. Establishments in this industry resell telecommunications;
they do not operate transmission facilities and infrastructure. Mobile
virtual network operators (MVNOs) are included in this industry. Under
that size standard, such a business is small if it has 1,500 or fewer
employees. Census data for 2012 show that 1,341 firms provided resale
services during that year. Of that number, all operated with fewer than
1,000 employees. Thus, under this category and the associated small
business size standard, the majority of these prepaid calling card
providers can be considered small entities.
157. Toll Resellers. The Commission has not developed a definition
for Toll Resellers. The closest NAICS Code Category is
Telecommunications Resellers. The Telecommunications Resellers industry
comprises establishments engaged in purchasing access and network
capacity from owners and operators of telecommunications networks and
reselling wired and wireless telecommunications services (except
satellite) to businesses and households. Establishments in this
industry resell telecommunications; they do not operate transmission
facilities and infrastructure. Mobile virtual network operators (MVNOs)
are included in this industry. The SBA has developed a small business
size standard for the category of Telecommunications Resellers. Under
that size standard, such a business is small if it has 1,500 or fewer
employees. Census data for 2012 show that 1,341 firms provided resale
services during that year. Of that number, 1,341 operated with fewer
than 1,000 employees. Thus, under this category and the associated
small business size standard, the majority of these resellers can be
considered small entities. According to Commission data, 881 carriers
have reported that they are engaged in the provision of toll resale
services. Of this total, an estimated 857 have 1,500 or fewer
employees. Consequently, the Commission estimates that the majority of
toll resellers are small entities.
158. Other Toll Carriers. Neither the Commission nor the SBA has
developed a definition for small businesses specifically applicable to
Other Toll Carriers. This category includes toll carriers that do not
fall within the categories of interexchange carriers, operator service
providers, prepaid calling card providers, satellite service carriers,
or toll resellers. The closest applicable NAICS Code category is for
Wired Telecommunications Carriers as defined above. Under the
applicable SBA size standard, such a business is small if it has 1,500
or fewer employees. Census data for 2012 show that there were 3,117
firms that operated that year. Of this total, 3,083 operated with fewer
than 1,000 employees. Thus, under this category and the associated
small business size standard, the majority of Other Toll Carriers can
be considered small. According to internally developed Commission data,
284 companies reported that their primary telecommunications service
activity was the provision of other toll carriage. Of these, an
estimated 279 have 1,500 or fewer employees. Consequently, the
Commission estimates that most Other Toll Carriers are small entities
that may be affected by rules adopted pursuant to the Order.
159. Operator Service Providers (OSPs). Neither the Commission nor
the SBA has developed a small business size standard specifically for
operator service providers. The appropriate size standard under SBA
rules is for the category Wired Telecommunications Carriers. Under that
size standard, such a business is small if it has 1,500 or fewer
employees. According to Commission data, 33 carriers have reported that
they are engaged in the provision of operator services. Of these, an
estimated 31 have 1,500 or fewer employees and two have more than 1,500
employees. Consequently, the Commission estimates that the majority of
OSPs are small entities.
4. Wireless Providers--Fixed and Mobile
160. Wireless Telecommunications Carriers (except Satellite). This
industry comprises establishments engaged in operating and maintaining
switching and transmission facilities to provide communications via the
airwaves. Establishments in this industry have spectrum licenses and
provide services using that spectrum, such as cellular services, paging
services, wireless internet access, and wireless video services. The
appropriate size standard under SBA rules is that such a business is
small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees. For this industry, U.S.
Census data for 2012 show that there were 967 firms that operated for
the entire year. Of this total, 955 firms had employment of 999 or
fewer employees and 12 had employment of 1000 employees or more. Thus
under this category and the associated size standard, the Commission
estimates that the majority of wireless telecommunications carriers
(except satellite) are small entities.
161. The Commission's own data--available in its Universal
Licensing System--indicate that, as of October 25, 2016, there are 280
Cellular licensees that will be affected by our actions today. The
Commission does not know how many of these licensees are small, as the
Commission does not collect that information for these types of
entities. Similarly, according to internally developed Commission data,
413 carriers reported that they were engaged in the provision of
wireless telephony, including cellular service, Personal Communications
Service, and Specialized Mobile Radio Telephony services. Of this
total, an estimated 261 have 1,500 or fewer employees, and 152 have
more than 1,500 employees. Thus, using available data, we estimate that
the majority of wireless firms can be considered small.
162. Wireless Communications Services. This service can be used for
fixed, mobile, radiolocation, and digital audio broadcasting satellite
uses. The Commission defined ``small business'' for the wireless
communications services (WCS) auction as an entity with average gross
revenues of $40 million for each of the three preceding years, and a
``very small business'' as an entity with average gross revenues of $15
million for each of the three preceding years. The SBA has approved
these definitions.
163. Wireless Telephony. Wireless telephony includes cellular,
personal communications services, and specialized mobile radio
telephony carriers. As noted, the SBA has developed a small business
size standard for Wireless Telecommunications Carriers (except
Satellite). Under the SBA small business size standard, a business is
small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees. According to Commission data,
413 carriers reported that they were engaged in wireless telephony. Of
these, an estimated 261 have 1,500 or fewer employees and 152 have more
than 1,500 employees. Therefore, a little less than one third of these
entities can be considered small.
5. Cable Service Providers
164. Because section 706 requires us to monitor the deployment of
broadband using any technology, we anticipate that
[[Page 67119]]
some broadband service providers may not provide telephone service.
Accordingly, we describe below other types of firms that may provide
broadband services, including cable companies, MDS providers, and
utilities, among others.
165. Cable and Other Subscription Programming. This industry
comprises establishments primarily engaged in operating studios and
facilities for the broadcasting of programs on a subscription or fee
basis. The broadcast programming is typically narrowcast in nature
(e.g. limited format, such as news, sports, education, or youth-
oriented). These establishments produce programming in their own
facilities or acquire programming from external sources. The
programming material is usually delivered to a third party, such as
cable systems or direct-to-home satellite systems, for transmission to
viewers. The SBA has established a size standard for this industry
stating that a business in this industry is small if it has 1,500 or
fewer employees. The 2012 Economic Census indicates that 367 firms were
operational for that entire year. Of this total, 357 operated with less
than 1,000 employees. Accordingly, we conclude that a substantial
majority of firms in this industry are small under the applicable SBA
size standard.
166. Cable Companies and Systems (Rate Regulation). The Commission
has developed its own small business size standards for the purpose of
cable rate regulation. Under the Commission's rules, a ``small cable
company'' is one serving 400,000 or fewer subscribers nationwide.
Industry data indicate that there are currently 4,600 active cable
systems in the United States. Of this total, all but eleven cable
operators nationwide are small under the 400,000-subscriber size
standard. In addition, under the Commission's rate regulation rules, a
``small system'' is a cable system serving 15,000 or fewer subscribers.
Current Commission records show 4,600 cable systems nationwide. Of this
total, 3,900 cable systems have fewer than 15,000 subscribers, and 700
systems have 15,000 or more subscribers, based on the same records.
Thus, under this standard as well, we estimate that most cable systems
are small entities.
167. Cable System Operators (Telecom Act Standard). The
Communications Act also contains a size standard for small cable system
operators, which is ``a cable operator that, directly or through an
affiliate, serves in the aggregate fewer than 1% of all subscribers in
the United States and is not affiliated with any entity or entities
whose gross annual revenues in the aggregate exceed $250,000,000.''
There are approximately 52,403,705 cable video subscribers in the
United States today. Accordingly, an operator serving fewer than
524,037 subscribers shall be deemed a small operator if its annual
revenues, when combined with the total annual revenues of all its
affiliates, do not exceed $250 million in the aggregate. Based on
available data, we find that all but nine incumbent cable operators are
small entities under this size standard. The Commission neither
requests nor collects information on whether cable system operators are
affiliated with entities whose gross annual revenues exceed $250
million. Although it seems certain that some of these cable system
operators are affiliated with entities whose gross annual revenues
exceed $250 million, we are unable at this time to estimate with
greater precision the number of cable system operators that would
qualify as small cable operators under the definition in the
Communications Act.
168. All Other Telecommunications. ``All Other Telecommunications''
is defined as follows: This U.S. industry is comprised of
establishments that are primarily engaged in providing specialized
telecommunications services, such as satellite tracking, communications
telemetry, and radar station operation. This industry also includes
establishments primarily engaged in providing satellite terminal
stations and associated facilities connected with one or more
terrestrial systems and capable of transmitting telecommunications to,
and receiving telecommunications from, satellite systems.
Establishments providing internet services or voice over internet
protocol (VoIP) services via client-supplied telecommunications
connections are also included in this industry. The SBA has developed a
small business size standard for ``All Other Telecommunications,''
which consists of all such firms with gross annual receipts of $32.5
million or less. For this category, census data for 2012 show that
there were 1,442 firms that operated for the entire year. Of these
firms, a total of 1,400 had gross annual receipts of less than $25
million. Consequently, we estimate that the majority of All Other
Telecommunications firms are small entities that might be affected by
our action.
E. Description of Projected Reporting, Recordkeeping, and Other
Compliance Requirements for Small Entities
169. Recordkeeping and Reporting. The rule revisions adopted in the
Order include changes that will require electing rate-of-return
carriers receiving fixed universal service support to make various
revisions to their business data service tariffs. For example, rate-of-
return carriers receiving fixed support that elect incentive regulation
will be required to file Tariff Review Plans and incentive regulation
tariffs for their lower capacity TDM BDS. Packet-based BDS and higher
capacity TDM BDS end user channel termination and lower capacity TDM
BDS end user channel terminations offered by electing carriers in study
areas deemed competitive by a competitive market test will be relieved
of ex ante pricing regulation and will be subject to permissive
detariffing for a period of 36 months at which time they will be
subject to mandatory detariffing.
170. The Commission also incorporates a productivity factor (X-
factor) of 2.0% and GDP-PI as the inflation factor used to adjust price
cap indexes in the first year of incentive regulation, and each year
thereafter for electing carriers. Electing carriers will be required to
revise their rates and tariff review plans for business data services
in filings with the Commission to reflect the new X-factor. Finally,
the Commission grants forbearance from the requirement in Sec. 54.1305
of our rules annually to report unseparated loop costs and other
accounting data to NECA.
F. Steps Taken To Minimize the Significant Economic Impact on Small
Entities and Significant Alternatives Considered
171. The RFA requires an agency to describe any significant
alternatives that it has considered in reaching its proposed approach,
which may include (among others) the following four alternatives: (1)
The establishment of differing compliance or reporting requirements or
timetables that take into account the resources available to small
entities; (2) the clarification, consolidation, or simplification of
compliance or reporting requirements under the rule for small entities;
(3) the use of performance, rather than design, standards; and (4) an
exemption from coverage of the rule, or any part thereof, for small
entities.
172. Incentive Regulation. In the Order, the Commission sheds
burdensome rate-of-return regulation in favor of lighter touch
incentive regulation for electing carriers' lower capacity TDM
transport and end user channel termination services. Additionally, the
Commission adopted the proposal in the NPRM to grant pricing
flexibility to electing carriers' lower capacity TDM transport and end
user channel termination services under
[[Page 67120]]
incentive regulation similar to the pricing flexibility the Commission
granted to price cap carriers' lower capacity TDM end user channel
terminations in areas deemed non-competitive in the BDS Order. The
pricing flexibility available to electing carriers, most of which are
small entities, will enable them to sell their BDS using contract
tariffs and term and volume discounts, enhancing their ability to
respond to competition.
173. Competitive Market Test. The Commission sought comment on four
options for a competitive market test for electing rate-of-return
carriers that receive fixed support. The option we selected is one of
the least burdensome options and relies on existing Form 477 data,
avoiding any additional burdensome data collection. We did not adopt
the proposal to use both prongs of the BDS Order competitive market
test to assess the competitiveness of study areas served by rate-of-
return carriers that receive fixed support despite its apparent
simplicity because we found methodological and conceptual flaws in the
proposal and in the study submitted by Petitioners to support the
proposal. Among the flaws the Commission identified is that the study
does not claim to be based on a representative sample of model-based
rate-of-return carriers that receive fixed support, the study compares
non-urbanized price cap areas with model-based rate-of-return areas
that in some instances include urbanized areas, and some of the
relevant counties included in the study were deemed non-competitive by
the price cap competitive market test. Further, the Commission declined
to adopt the other two options from the NPRM which would have required
costly, time consuming, burdensome data collections. Instead, the Order
found that the record supports adopting the second option from the NPRM
which uses the second prong of the BDS Order competitive market test
that is based on Form 477 data. As a result, ex ante pricing regulation
of lower capacity TDM end user channel terminations will no longer
apply in study areas served by rate-of-return carriers that receive
fixed support that are deemed competitive.
174. Packet-based and Higher Capacity TDM Business Data Services.
The Commission removed ex ante pricing regulation for electing rate-of-
return carriers' packet-based and higher capacity TDM business data
services and directed electing carriers to detariff these services
following a transition period. This action is consistent with the
Commission's preference to minimize the burdens of regulation.
175. X-factor. Rate-of-return carriers that receive fixed support
that elect incentive regulation are required to file revised annual
access charge tariffs every year, which become effective on July 1. The
annual filings include submission of tariff review plans that are used
to support revisions to the rates, including revisions that pertain to
the X-factor. To ease the burden on the industry in connection with
this filing, and because base period demand and the value of GDP-PI
reflected in the price cap indices typically are not updated during a
tariff year, the Commission permits electing carriers to use, in their
filings implementing the 2.0% X-factor, the same base period demand and
value of GDP-PI as in the prior year's annual filing.
176. Periodic Revision to Competitive Market Test. Related to the
competitive market test proposal, the Commission also proposed future
periodic data collections to allow for market test updates for
determining competitive and non-competitive areas. The periodic
collections could have resulted in a significant reporting burden on
small entities. Instead, the Commission adopted a process for updating
the competitive market test every three years using the data from Form
477 that is already routinely filed by providers and thus entails no
additional recordkeeping or reporting burden.
177. Forbearance. The Commission granted forbearance, pursuant to
section 10 of the Act, from the Cost Assignment Rules for electing
carriers, subject to the requirement relating to the calculation of
pole attachment rates. The Commission found that the Cost Assignment
Rules are no longer necessary to ensure that charges and practices are
just, reasonable, and not unjustly or unreasonably discriminatory; to
protect consumers; and to protect the public interest. The Commission
found that the rules were no longer necessary for carriers converting
to incentive regulation and that eliminating unnecessary regulation
will generally reduce providers' costs and provide a more level playing
field because other providers of similar services are not subject to
these requirements.
178. Detariffing. To minimize economic impact, the Commission
provides a transition period to provide electing rate-of-return
carriers that receive fixed support with sufficient time to detariff
their business data services. The Commission does not intend its
actions to disturb existing contractual or other long-term
arrangements, which it grandfathered and which continue to remain in
effect for the length of the contract.
G. Report to Congress
179. The Commission will send a copy of the Report and Order,
including this FRFA, in a report to be sent to Congress pursuant to the
Congressional Review Act. In addition, the Commission will send a copy
of the Report and Order, including this FRFA, to the Chief Counsel for
Advocacy of the SBA. A copy of the Order and FRFA (or summaries
thereof) will also be published in the Federal Register.
V. Procedural Matters
180. Paperwork Reduction Act Analysis. It was determined that the
final rule makes only non-substantive changes to currently approved
information collections and therefore does not require separate
Paperwork Reduction Act approval. The rules are effective 60 days after
publication in the Federal Register. In addition, we note that pursuant
to the Small Business Paperwork Relief Act of 2002, we previously
sought specific comment on how the Commission might further reduce the
information collection burden for small business concerns with fewer
than 25 employees. We describe impacts that might affect small
businesses, which includes most businesses with fewer than 25
employees, in the Final Regulatory Flexibility Analysis in Section IV
above.
181. Congressional Review Act. The Commission will send a copy of
this Report and Order to Congress and the Government Accountability
Office pursuant to the Congressional Review Act, see 5 U.S.C.
801(a)(1)(A).
182. Final Regulatory Flexibility Analysis. As required by the
Regulatory Flexibility Act (RFA), an Initial Regulatory Flexibility
Analysis (IRFA) was incorporated into the NPRM. The Commission sought
written public comment on the possible significant economic impact on
small entities regarding the proposals addressed in the NPRM, including
comments on the IRFA. Pursuant to the RFA, a Final Regulatory
Flexibility Analysis is set forth in Section IV above.
183. Contact Person. For further information about this proceeding,
please contact Justin Faulb, FCC Wireline Competition Bureau, Pricing
Policy Division, 445 12th Street SW, Washington, DC 20554, (202) 418-
1589, Justin.Faulb@fcc.gov.
VI. Ordering Clauses
184. Accordingly, it is ordered that, pursuant to sections 1, 2,
4(i)-(j), 10, 201(b), 202(a), 214, 303(r), 403, of the
[[Page 67121]]
Communications Act of 1934, as amended, and section 706 of the
Telecommunications Act of 1996, 47 U.S.C. 151, 152, 154(i)-(j), 160,
201(b), 202(a), 214, 303(r), 403, 1302, this Report and Order IS
ADOPTED and shall be effective sixty (60) days after publication in the
Federal Register, except to the extent expressly addressed below.
185. It is further ordered that parts 1, 32, 51, 61, and 69 of the
Commission's rules, 47 CFR parts 1, 32, 51, 61, and 69, are amended as
set forth below, and that such rule amendments shall be effective sixty
(60) days after publication of this Report and Order in the Federal
Register.
186. It is further ordered that pursuant to sections 201(b) and
202(a) of the Communications Act of 1934, as amended, 47 U.S.C. 201(b),
202(a), rate-of-return carriers electing to offer business data
services shall freeze the tariffed rates for packet-based and higher
capacity TDM services and for TDM end-user channel terminations at or
below a DS3 in study areas deemed competitive that the rate-of-return
carrier continues to tariff for six (6) months following the applicable
effective date of the carrier's election.
187. It is further ordered that the Commission's Consumer &
Governmental Affairs Bureau, Reference Information Center, shall send a
copy of this Report and Order to Congress and the Government
Accountability Office pursuant to the Congressional Review Act, see 5
U.S.C. 801(a)(1)(A).
188. It is further ordered, that the Commission's Consumer &
Governmental Affairs Bureau, Reference Information Center, shall send a
copy of this Report and Order to the Chief Counsel for Advocacy of the
Small Business Administration.
List of Subjects
47 CFR Part 1
Communications common carriers, Reporting and recordkeeping,
Telecommunications.
47 CFR Part 32
Communications, Reporting and recordkeeping requirements,
Telephone, Uniform System of Accounts.
47 CFR Part 51
Communications common carriers, Telecommunications.
47 CFR Part 61
Communications common carriers, Radio, Reporting and recordkeeping
requirements, Telegraph, Telephone.
47 CFR Part 69
Communications common carriers, Reporting and recordkeeping
requirements, Telephone.
Federal Communications Commission
Marlene Dortch,
Secretary.
RULES
The Federal Communications Commission amends 47 CFR parts 1, 32,
51, 61, and 69 as follows:
PART 1--PRACTICE AND PROCEDURE
0
1. The authority citation for part 1 continues to read as follows:
Authority: 47 U.S.C. 151, 154(i) and (j), 155, 157, 160, 201,
224, 225, 227, 303, 309, 310, 332, 1403, 1404, 1451, 1452, and 1455.
0
2. Section 1.1406 is amended by adding paragraph (e) to read as
follows:
Sec. 1.1406 Commission consideration of the complaint.
* * * * *
(e) A price cap company, or a rate-of-return carrier electing to
provide service pursuant to Sec. 61.50 of this chapter, that opts-out
of part 32 of this chapter may calculate attachment rates for its
poles, ducts, conduits, and rights of way using either part 32
accounting data or GAAP accounting data. A company using GAAP
accounting data to compute rates to attach to its poles, ducts,
conduits, and rights of way in any of the first twelve years after
opting-out must adjust (increase or decrease) its annually computed
GAAP-based rates by an Implementation Rate Difference for each of the
remaining years in the period. The Implementation Rate Difference means
the difference between attachment rates calculated by the carrier under
part 32 and under GAAP as of the last full year preceding the carrier's
initial opting-out of part 32 USOA accounting requirements.
PART 32--UNIFORM SYSTEM OF ACCOUNTS FOR TELECOMMUNICATIONS
COMPANIES
0
3. The authority citation for part 32 continues to read as follows:
Authority: 47 U.S.C. 219, 220 as amended, unless otherwise
noted.
0
4. Section 32.1 is revised to read as follows:
Sec. 32.1 Background.
The revised Uniform System of Accounts (USOA) is a historical
financial accounting system which reports the results of operational
and financial events in a manner which enables both management and
regulators to assess these results within a specified accounting
period. The USOA also provides the financial community and others with
financial performance results. In order for an accounting system to
fulfill these purposes, it must exhibit consistency and stability in
financial reporting (including the results published for regulatory
purposes). Accordingly, the USOA has been designed to reflect stable,
recurring financial data based to the extent regulatory considerations
permit upon the consistency of the well-established body of accounting
theories and principles commonly referred to as generally accepted
accounting principles (GAAP). The rules of this part, and any other
rules or orders that are derivative of or dependent on the rules in
this part, do not apply to price cap companies, and rate-of-return
telephone companies offering business data services pursuant to Sec.
61.50 of this chapter, that have opted-out of USOA requirements
pursuant to the conditions specified by the Commission in Sec.
32.11(g).
0
5. Section 32.11 is amended by revising paragraph (g) to read as
follows:
Sec. 32.11 Companies subject to this part.
* * * * *
(g) Notwithstanding paragraph (a) of this section, a price cap
company, or a rate-of-return telephone company offering business data
services pursuant to Sec. 61.50 of this chapter, that elects to
calculate its pole attachment rates pursuant to Sec. 1.1406(e) of this
chapter will not be subject to this Uniform System of Accounts.
PART 51--INTERCONNECTION
0
6. The authority citation for part 51 continues to read as follows:
Authority: 47 U.S.C. 151-55, 201-05, 207-09, 218, 225-27, 251-
52, 271, 332 unless otherwise noted.
0
7. Section 51.903 is amended by revising paragraph (g) to read as
follows:
Sec. 51.903 Definitions.
* * * * *
(g) Rate-of-Return Carrier is any incumbent local exchange carrier
not subject to price cap regulation as that term is defined in Sec.
61.3(bb) of this chapter, but only with respect to the territory in
which it operates as an incumbent local exchange carrier.
* * * * *
PART 61--TARIFFS
0
8. The authority citation for part 61 continues to read as follows:
[[Page 67122]]
Authority: 47 U.S.C. 151, 154(i), 154(j), 201-05 and 403, unless
otherwise noted.
0
9. Section 61.41 is amended by revising paragraph (d) and adding
paragraph (f) to read as follows:
Sec. 61.41 Price cap requirements generally.
* * * * *
(d) Except as provided in paragraph (e) of this section, local
exchange carriers that become subject to price cap regulation as that
term is defined in Sec. 61.3(ff) shall not be eligible to withdraw
from such regulation.
* * * * *
(f) Notwithstanding the requirements of paragraphs (c) and (d) of
this section, a telephone company subject to rate-of-return regulation
that is affiliated with a price cap local exchange carrier may provide
business data services pursuant to Sec. 61.50 without converting other
services to price cap regulation.
0
10. Section 61.50 is added to read as follows:
Sec. 61.50 Regulation of business data services offered by rate-of-
return carriers electing incentive regulation.
(a) A rate-of-return carrier, as defined in Sec. 51.903(g) of this
chapter, may elect to offer its business data services subject to
incentive regulation pursuant to this section. A rate-of-return carrier
may elect to offer business data services subject to incentive
regulation pursuant to this section only if all affiliated rate-of-
return carriers meeting the requirements of paragraph (b) of this
section make the election. A carrier's election under this section is
irrevocable.
(b) A rate-of-return carrier is eligible to elect incentive
regulation for its business data services if the carrier:
(1) Receives universal service payments pursuant to the
Alternative-Connect America Cost Model pursuant to Sec. 54.311 of this
chapter;
(2) Is an affiliate of a price cap local exchange carrier operating
pursuant to a waiver of Sec. 61.41;
(3) Receives universal service payments pursuant to Sec. 54.306 of
this chapter; or
(4) Transitions away from legacy support mechanisms in the future.
(c) A rate-of-return carrier electing to offer business data
services pursuant to this section shall employ the procedures outlined
in Sec. Sec. 61.42 through 61.49 to calculate rates for its business
data services and adjust its indexes for those rates to the extent
those sections are applicable to business data services, except that:
(1) Exogenous costs associated with regulated services shall be
allocated to business data services based on relative regulated
business data services revenues, compared to regulated revenues and
related support receipts; and
(2) An electing carrier is not required to file a short form tariff
review plan as required by Sec. 61.49(k).
(d) A rate-of-return carrier electing to offer business data
services pursuant to this section must remove its business data
services from the NECA Traffic Sensitive Pool. Such a carrier may
continue to participate in the NECA Traffic Sensitive Pool and tariff
for access services other than business data services.
(e) A rate-of-return carrier offering business data services
pursuant to this section may offer those business data services at
different rates in different study areas.
(f) A rate-of-return carrier offering business data services
pursuant to this section may make a low-end adjustment pursuant to
Sec. 61.45(d)(1)(vii) unless it:
(1) Exercises the regulatory relief pursuant to paragraph (g) of
this section in any part of its service region; or
(2) Exercises the option to use Generally Accepted Accounting
Principles rather than the part 32 Uniform System of Accounts pursuant
to Sec. 32.11(g) of this chapter.
(g) A rate-of-return carrier electing to offer business data
services pursuant to this section may offer time division multiplexed
transport and end user channel termination services at or below a DS3
bandwidth that include:
(1) Volume and term discounts;
(2) Contract-based tariffs, provided that:
(i) Contract-based tariff services are made generally available to
all similarly situated customers; and
(ii) The rate-of-return carrier excludes all contract-based tariff
offerings from incentive regulation; and
(3) The ability to file tariff revisions on at least one day's
notice, notwithstanding the notice requirements for tariff filings
specified in Sec. 61.58.
(h) A rate-of-return carrier electing to offer business data
services pursuant to this section shall comply with the requirements of
Sec. 69.805 of this chapter in its study areas deemed non-competitive
pursuant to this section.
(i) The regulation of other services offered by a carrier that
offers business data services pursuant to this section shall not be
modified as a result of the requirements of this section.
(j)(1) The Wireline Competition Bureau will conduct an initial
competitive market test for rate-of-return carriers eligible to elect
incentive regulation pursuant to this section. Study areas of such
carriers will be deemed competitive if 75 percent of the census blocks
within the study area are reported to have a minimum of 10 Mbps
download and 1 Mbps upload broadband service offered by a cable
operator based on the most current publicly available Form 477 data. A
list of study areas deemed competitive by the competitive market test
will be published on the Commission's website.
(2) The Wireline Competition Bureau will conduct subsequent
competitive market tests for rate-of-return carriers electing incentive
regulation pursuant to this section contemporaneously with the
subsequent tests mandated by Sec. 69.803 of this chapter for price cap
carriers.
(3) A study area of an electing carrier deemed competitive by the
competitive market test will retain its status in subsequent tests.
(k)(1) Packet-based and time division multiplexed business data
services above a DS3 bandwidth offered by a rate-of-return carrier
pursuant to this section shall not be subject to ex ante pricing
regulation.
(2) Time division multiplexed end user channel termination business
data services at or below a DS3 bandwidth offered by a rate-of-return
carrier pursuant to this section in study areas deemed competitive by
the competitive market test shall not be subject to ex ante pricing
regulation.
(3) A rate-of-return carrier electing incentive regulation for its
business data services must detariff:
(i) All packet-based and time division multiplexed business data
services above a DS3 bandwidth within thirty-six months after the
effective date of its election of incentive regulation; and
(ii) All time division multiplexed end user channel termination
business data services at or below a DS3 bandwidth in any study area
deemed competitive by the competitive market test within thirty-six
months after such services shall be deemed competitive in a study area.
(l)(1) A rate-of-return carrier electing incentive regulation for
its business data services effective July 1, 2019 must notify the Chief
of the Wireline Competition Bureau of its election by May 1, 2019 for
it to become effective concurrent with the annual access tariff filing
in 2019.
(2) A rate-of-return carrier electing incentive regulation for its
business data services effective July 1, 2020 must notify the Chief of
the Wireline Competition Bureau of its election by May 1, 2020 for it
to become effective concurrent with the annual access tariff filing in
2020.
[[Page 67123]]
(3) A rate-of-return carrier accepting future offers of
Alternative-Connect America Cost Model support or otherwise
transitioning away from legacy support mechanisms and electing
incentive regulation for its business data services must notify the
Chief of the Wireline Competition Bureau of its election by May 1
following its acceptance of the offer for it to become effective
concurrent with that year's annual access tariff filing.
0
11. Section 61.55 is amended by revising paragraph (a) to read as
follows:
Sec. 61.55 Contract-based tariffs.
(a) This section shall apply to price cap local exchange carriers
permitted to offer contract-based tariffs under Sec. 1.776 or Sec.
69.805 of this chapter, as well as to the offering of business data
services by rate-of-return carriers pursuant to Sec. 61.50.
* * * * *
PART 69--ACCESS CHARGES
0
12. The authority citation for part 69 continues to read as follows:
Authority: 47 U.S.C. 154, 201, 202, 203, 205, 218, 220, 254,
403.
0
13. Section 69.114 is amended by revising paragraph (a) to read as
follows:
Sec. 69.114 Special access.
(a) Appropriate subelements shall be established for the use of
equipment or facilities that are assigned to the Special Access element
for purposes of apportioning net investment, or that are equivalent to
such equipment or facilities for companies subject to price cap
regulation as that term is defined in Sec. 61.3(ff) of this chapter.
* * * * *
[FR Doc. 2018-27528 Filed 12-27-18; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6712-01-P