Use of Spectrum Bands Above 24 GHz for Mobile Radio Services, 42089-42099 [2018-17820]
Download as PDF
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 161 / Monday, August 20, 2018 / Proposed Rules
For each . . .
For the following . . .
You must demonstrate continuous compliance
by . . .
12. Sanitaryware shuttle
kiln.
a. Minimize HAP emissions.
i. Maintaining records documenting your use of natural gas, or an equivalent fuel, as the kiln fuel at
all times except during periods of natural gas curtailment or supply interruption; and
ii. If you intend to use an alternative fuel, submitting
a notification of alternative fuel use within 48
hours of the declaration of a period of natural gas
curtailment or supply interruption, as defined in
§ 63.8665; and
iii. Submitting a report of alternative fuel use within
10 working days after terminating the use of the
alternative fuel, as specified in § 63.8635(g); and
iv. Using a designed firing time and temperature
cycle for each sanitaryware shuttle kiln; and
v. For each firing load, documenting the total tonnage of greenware placed in the kiln to ensure
that it is not greater than the maximum load identified in Item 1.a.iii of Table 3 to this subpart; and
vi. Following maintenance procedures for each kiln
that, at a minimum, specify the frequency of inspection and maintenance of temperature monitoring devices, controls that regulate air-to-fuel ratios, and controls that regulate firing cycles; and
vii. Developing and maintaining records for each
sanitaryware shuttle kiln, as specified in
§ 63.8640.
BILLING CODE 6560–50–P
FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS
COMMISSION
47 CFR Part 30
[GN Docket No. 14–177; FCC 18–110]
Use of Spectrum Bands Above 24 GHz
for Mobile Radio Services
Federal Communications
Commission.
ACTION: Proposed rule.
AGENCY:
In this document, a Fourth
Notice of Proposed Rulemaking (4th
FNPRM) invites members of the public
to comment on how best to transition
existing spectrum holdings in the 39
GHz band to the new flexible-use band
plan, and on using an incentive auction
mechanism. The Federal
Communications Commission
(Commission or FCC) proposes to
modify the 39 GHz, Upper 37 GHz, and
47 GHz band plans from 200 megahertz
to 100 megahertz channels to facilitate
the auctioning of all three bands at the
same time. The Commission also
proposes an incentive auction to reduce
encumbrances and create contiguous
blocks of spectrum through the 39 GHz
and Upper 37 GHz bands. These
proposals will promote the efficient use
of this spectrum by incumbents and
new licensees.
DATES: Comments are due on or before
September 17, 2018, and reply
comments are due on or before October
8, 2018.
SUMMARY:
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:07 Aug 17, 2018
Jkt 244001
You may submit comments,
identified by GN Docket No. 14–177, by
any of the following methods:
• Federal eRulemaking Portal: https://
www.regulations.gov. Follow the
instructions for submitting comments.
• Federal Communications
Commission’s website: https://
www.fcc.gov/ecfs/. Follow the
instructions for submitting comments.
• People with Disabilities: Contact the
FCC to request reasonable
accommodations (accessible format
documents, sign language interpreters,
CART, etc.) by email: FCC504@fcc.gov,
phone: 202–418–0530 or TTY: 202–418–
0432.
For detailed instructions for
submitting comments and additional
information on the rulemaking process,
see the SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION
section of this document.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: Erik
Salovaara, Wireless
Telecommunications Bureau, Auctions
and Spectrum Access Division, (202)
418–0660, Erik.Salovaara@fcc.gov or
Simon Banyai, Wireless
Telecommunications Bureau,
Broadband Division, (202) 418–1443,
Simon.Banyai@fcc.gov.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: This is a
summary of the Commission’s 4th
Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking
(4th FNPRM), GN Docket No. 14–177,
FCC 18–110, adopted on August 2,
2018, and released on August 3, 2018.
The complete text of this document is
available for public inspection and
copying from 8 a.m. to 4:30 p.m. Eastern
Time (ET) Monday through Thursday or
from 8 a.m. to 11:30 a.m. ET on Fridays
in the FCC Reference Information
ADDRESSES:
[FR Doc. 2018–17933 Filed 8–17–18; 8:45 am]
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with PROPOSALS
42089
PO 00000
Frm 00028
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
Or by . .
Center, 445 12th Street SW, Room CY–
A257, Washington, DC 20554. The
complete text is also available on the
Commission’s website at https://
wireless.fcc.gov, or by using the search
function on the ECFS web page at
https://www.fcc.gov/cgb/ecfs/.
Alternative formats are available to
persons with disabilities by sending an
email to fcc504@fcc.gov or by calling the
Consumer & Governmental Affairs
Bureau at (202) 418–0530 (voice), (202)
418–0432 (tty).
Comment Filing Procedures
Pursuant to §§ 1.415 and 1.419 of the
Commission’s rules, 47 CFR 1.415,
1.419, interested parties may file
comments and reply comments on or
before the dates indicated on the first
page of this document. Comments may
be filed using the Commission’s
Electronic Comment Filing System
(ECFS). See Electronic Filing of
Documents in Rulemaking Proceedings,
63 FR 24121 (1998).
• Electronic Filers: Comments may be
filed electronically using the internet by
accessing the ECFS: https://
www.fcc.gov/ecfs/filings. Filers should
follow the instructions provided on the
website for submitting comments. In
completing the transmittal screen, filers
should include their full name, U.S.
Postal Service mailing address, and the
applicable docket number, GN Docket
No. 14–177.
• Paper Filers: Parties who choose to
file by paper must file an original and
one copy of each filing. If more than one
docket or rulemaking number appears in
the caption of this proceeding, filers
must submit two additional copies for
E:\FR\FM\20AUP1.SGM
20AUP1
42090
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 161 / Monday, August 20, 2018 / Proposed Rules
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with PROPOSALS
each additional docket or rulemaking
number.
Filings can be sent by hand or
messenger delivery, by commercial
overnight courier, or by first-class or
overnight U.S. Postal Service mail. All
filings must be addressed to the
Commission’s Secretary, Office of the
Secretary, Federal Communications
Commission.
• All hand-delivered or messengerdelivered paper filings for the
Commission’s Secretary must be
delivered to FCC Headquarters at 445
12th St. SW, Room TW–A325,
Washington, DC 20554. The filing hours
are 8:00 a.m. to 7:00 p.m. All hand
deliveries must be held together with
rubber bands or fasteners. Any
envelopes and boxes must be disposed
of before entering the building.
• Commercial overnight mail (other
than U.S. Postal Service Express Mail
and Priority Mail) must be sent to 9050
Junction Dr., Annapolis Junction,
Annapolis, MD 20701.
• U.S. Postal Service first-class,
Express, and Priority mail must be
addressed to 445 12th Street SW,
Washington, DC 20554.
People with Disabilities: To request
materials in accessible formats for
people with disabilities (braille, large
print, electronic files, audio format),
send an email to fcc504@fcc.gov or call
the Consumer & Governmental Affairs
Bureau at 202–418–0530 (voice), 888–
835–5322 (tty).
Ex Parte Rules—Permit-But-Disclose
Pursuant to § 1.1200(a) of the
Commission’s rules, this 4th FNPRM
shall be treated as a ‘‘permit-butdisclose’’ proceeding in accordance
with the Commission’s ex parte rules.
Persons making ex parte presentations
must file a copy of any written
presentation or a memorandum
summarizing any oral presentation
within two business days after the
presentation (unless a different deadline
applicable to the Sunshine period
applies). Persons making oral ex parte
presentations are reminded that
memoranda summarizing the
presentation must (1) list all persons
attending or otherwise participating in
the meeting at which the ex parte
presentation was made, and (2)
summarize all data presented and
arguments made during the
presentation. If the presentation
consisted in whole or in part of the
presentation of data or arguments
already reflected in the presenter’s
written comments, memoranda or other
filings in the proceeding, the presenter
may provide citations to such data or
arguments in his or her prior comments,
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:07 Aug 17, 2018
Jkt 244001
memoranda, or other filings (specifying
the relevant page and/or paragraph
numbers where such data or arguments
can be found) in lieu of summarizing
them in the memorandum. Documents
shown or given to Commission staff
during ex parte meetings are deemed to
be written ex parte presentations and
must be filed consistent with
§ 1.1206(b). In proceedings governed by
§ 1.49(f) or for which the Commission
has made available a method of
electronic filing, written ex parte
presentations and memoranda
summarizing oral ex parte
presentations, and all attachments
thereto, must be filed through the
electronic comment filing system
available for that proceeding, and must
be filed in their native format (e.g., .doc,
.xml, .ppt, searchable .pdf). Participants
in this proceeding should familiarize
themselves with the Commission’s ex
parte rules.
Initial Regulatory Flexibility Analysis
As required by the Regulatory
Flexibility Act of 1980, as amended
(RFA), the Commission has prepared
this present Initial Regulatory
Flexibility Analysis (IRFA) of the
possible significant economic impact on
a substantial number of small entities by
the policies and rules proposed in the
attached 4th FNPRM. Written public
comments are requested on this IRFA.
Comments must be identified as
responses to the IRFA and must be filed
by the deadlines for comments as
specified in the 4th FNPRM. The
Commission will send a copy of this 4th
FNPRM, including this IRFA, to the
Chief Counsel for Advocacy of the Small
Business Administration (SBA). In
addition, the 4th FNPRM and IRFA (or
summaries thereof) will be published in
the Federal Register.
Paperwork Reduction Act
The 4th FNPRM seeks comment on
potential new or revised information
collection requirements. If the
Commission adopts any new or revised
information collection requirements, the
Commission will publish a notice in the
Federal Register inviting the public to
comment on the requirements, as
required by the Paperwork Reduction
Act of 1995, Public Law 104–13 (44
U.S.C. 3501–3520). In addition,
pursuant to the Small Business
Paperwork Relief Act of 2002, Public
Law 107–198, see 44 U.S.C. 3506(c)(4),
the Commission seeks specific comment
on how it might ‘‘further reduce the
information collection burden for small
business concerns with fewer than 25
employees.’’
PO 00000
Frm 00029
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
Synopsis
I. Band Plan
1. We propose to modify the 39 GHz
band plan from seven 200 megahertz
channels to fourteen 100 megahertz
channels. This change should better
accommodate the repacking of
incumbents, which in the vast majority
of cases, hold two non-contiguous 50
megahertz license blocks for each
original paired license (now unpaired).
Given the natural fit between
incumbents’ existing 100 megahertz
holdings and the proposed 100
megahertz channels, the resulting
realignment process for incumbents
would be less complex than using 200
megahertz channels, because it would
result in far fewer partially-filled
channels. This change therefore would
further our goals of maximizing efficient
use of this band and allowing this
spectrum to be put to use as soon as
possible.
2. Further, changing the band plan
from 200 megahertz channels to 100
megahertz channels should not limit
this spectrum’s potential use for 5G
services. The 100 megahertz channels
are consistent with 3GPP standards, and
licensees can aggregate to larger channel
sizes (such as 200 megahertz, 300
megahertz, etc.), should they prefer to
do so. Given that 100 megahertz is the
baseline to provide 5G services, the
Commission has adopted 100 megahertz
channels for other UMFUS bands,
including the 24 GHz band and Lower
37 GHz (37.0–37.6) band, and we have
proposed to adopt 100 megahertz
channels for the 42 GHz band. Adopting
100 megahertz channels in the 39 GHz
band is consistent with our approach in
other mmW spectrum bands to support
5G services.
3. We similarly propose to modify the
band plan in the Upper 37 GHz band
(37.6–38.6 GHz) from 200 megahertz to
100 megahertz channels. The Upper 37
GHz band is adjacent to the 39 GHz
band, and both bands are under the
same licensing framework. In aligning
the regulatory regimes of these bands—
including implementing the same
service rules and an operability
requirement—the Commission has
effectively treated the two bands as one
contiguous 2,400 megahertz band of
spectrum. We further note that a
difference in channel size between the
two bands could create strategic
challenges and impede bidding
flexibility should the Commission
auction the two bands together.1
1 With respect to auctioning the Upper 37 GHz
band, we note that the Spectrum Frontiers 3rd
FNPRM is seeking comment on how best to
E:\FR\FM\20AUP1.SGM
20AUP1
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 161 / Monday, August 20, 2018 / Proposed Rules
4. We also propose to modify the band
plan for the portion of the 47 GHz band
licensed under the UMFUS rules, 47.2–
48.2 GHz (47 GHz band), from 200 to
100 megahertz channels. Modifying the
band plan for the 47 GHz band to 100
megahertz blocks would provide
consistency across the remaining
UMFUS bands not yet designated for
auction, and licensees can aggregate
spectrum licenses, should they desire
larger bandwidth. If we auction the 47
GHz band at the same time as we
auction the 39 GHz and Upper 37 GHz
bands, should all band plans be
consistent 100 megahertz blocks?
5. We seek comment on these
proposals. Commenters proposing
alternative band plans, including
retaining the current 200 megahertz
channels, should specify the benefits of
such a plan, particularly with respect to
how it would further our goal of making
contiguous spectrum blocks available
for both incumbents and new entrants.
II. Reducing Encumbrances in the 39
GHz Band
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with PROPOSALS
A. An Incentive Auction
6. We propose to reconfigure and
auction together licenses for all the
available spectrum in the Upper 37 GHz
and 39 GHz bands using an incentive
auction. We propose to run a clock
auction, in which incumbents and
others may participate, to set both the
price of new licenses and the amounts
for which incumbents will relinquish
their spectrum usage rights. This clock
auction would simultaneously serve as
the reverse and forward components of
the incentive auction. At the end of the
auction, participating incumbent
licensees would receive an incentive
payment based on their cancelled
incumbent licenses. The amount of the
incentive payment could be used as a
credit toward the licensees’ winning
bids for any new licenses in any of the
bands offered in the auction. Because
the Commission has not previously
conducted an incentive auction in this
way, we walk through each step in turn.
7. As an initial matter, we propose to
use a two-phase auction procedure. In
the first phase, participants would bid
to win generic spectrum blocks using an
ascending clock auction that would
determine a uniform price in each
accommodate coordination zones in the 37 GHz
band for future Federal operations at a limited
number of additional sites, and whether the
coordination zones previously established in
Section 30.205 might be reduced to better
accommodate nearby non-Federal operations
without adversely impacting Federal operations at
those sites. See Spectrum Frontiers 3rd FNPRM at
30, para. 74; Spectrum Frontiers R&O, 31 FCC Rcd
at 8070–71, para. 149.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:07 Aug 17, 2018
Jkt 244001
PEA—this encompasses the
simultaneous forward-and-reverse
auction. The second phase would assign
specific-frequency licenses by PEA that
would aim to ensure contiguity within
each PEA. Because unencumbered
spectrum blocks in the Upper 37 GHz
and 39 GHz bands can be treated as
largely interchangeable within a PEA,
we propose to offer these blocks as one
category of generic blocks in a clock
auction. We expect that using a clock
auction format with bidding for generic
blocks followed by an assignment phase
will speed up the auction considerably
relative to a typical FCC simultaneous
multiple-round auction.
8. Specifically, we propose to use a
clock auction design with rules similar
to those used for the forward auction in
the broadcast incentive auction and the
planned 24 GHz auction. Our proposed
clock auction format would proceed in
a series of rounds, with bidding being
conducted simultaneously for all
generic spectrum blocks available in the
auction. During the clock phase, the
auction would announce prices for
generic blocks in each PEA, and
qualified bidders would submit quantity
bids for the number of blocks they seek
in the PEA at that clock price. Bidding
rounds would be open for
predetermined periods of time, during
which bidders would indicate their
demands for blocks at the clock prices
associated with the current round.
Bidders would be subject to activity and
eligibility rules that govern the pace at
which they participate in the auction. In
each PEA, the clock price for licenses
would increase from round to round if
bidders indicate total demand that
exceeds the number of blocks available
in the category. Bidders would be held
to their bids, as in the forward phase of
the broadcast incentive auction, with
the system only allowing a bidder to
reduce demand if aggregate demand
would not fall below the available
supply of blocks in that PEA. The clock
rounds would continue until, for all
generic blocks in all geographic areas,
the number of blocks demanded does
not exceed the supply of available
blocks. At that point, those bidders
indicating demand for a block in a
category at the final clock phase price
would be deemed winning bidders.
9. Next, winning bidders from the
clock phase would have an opportunity
to submit sealed bids by PEA for
particular frequency blocks in a separate
assignment phase. We propose that this
assignment phase be voluntary:
Winning bidders need not bid in the
assignment phase. Regardless of its
participation in the assignment phase,
the assignment phase would aim to
PO 00000
Frm 00030
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
42091
assign contiguous frequency blocks
within a PEA to a bidder that wins
multiple blocks.
10. To encourage participation in the
reverse auction, we propose to offer
incumbents an incentive payment—
using what we term here a ‘‘voucher’’—
in exchange for the cancellation of
certain incumbent licenses at the end of
the auction. Each voucher would have
a dollar value equal to the final clock
phase price (for a single generic block
under the new band plan) in the PEA
times the ratio of the incumbent’s MHzpops to the MHz-pops in a full generic
block. We note that, by this definition,
a participating incumbent licensee with
a license for 100 megahertz of
unencumbered spectrum in a PEA could
receive a voucher precisely equal to the
cost of paying a winning bid for a
license for the same spectrum in the
forward auction. Accordingly,
participation in the clock auction by
incumbent licensees will
simultaneously be participation in the
forward and reverse auction: The bids
for new blocks in the forward auction
automatically set the price of vouchers
that participating incumbent licensees
may receive as vouchers in the reverse
auction. As the auction proceeds, the
incumbent licensee can elect whether to
pursue new licenses by placing new
bids in the forward auction or to accept
the voucher by requesting a reduction in
its demand. Thus, the auction to
determine the amount of the winning
bid for the new blocks also serves as the
reverse auction that determines the
incentive payment a licensee would
receive for voluntarily relinquishing
spectrum usage rights.
11. Although incumbent licensees
bidding in the auction would be free to
request a reduction in their demand at
any time during the auction based on
their expectations regarding the value of
their vouchers, the Commission itself
would not process vouchers until after
the clock auction is over. Provided that
the total auction proceeds exceed the
total incentive payments to be shared
with licensees relinquishing spectrum
usage rights, we can close the incentive
auction regardless of the proceeds or
relinquishments in a particular PEA.
Then, the Commission would process
vouchers for each incumbent licensee in
each PEA in two steps, depending on
whether all the spectrum made available
in the reverse auction was needed for
the forward auction. First, the
Commission would determine whether
demand at the end of the forward
auction equaled supply in any given
PEA; in those PEAs, the Commission
would cancel the participating
E:\FR\FM\20AUP1.SGM
20AUP1
42092
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 161 / Monday, August 20, 2018 / Proposed Rules
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with PROPOSALS
incumbents’ licenses and make
payments based on the vouchers.2
12. In the event that demand by
bidders in the forward auction in a PEA
is less than the total supply of blocks
offered, we need to address how to
prioritize the blocks supplied by
incumbent licensees relative to the
supply of blocks that are held by the
FCC in order to determine whether all
incumbent-supplied blocks can be
relinquished. That is, if bidders are
interested in obtaining fewer new
licenses than the total number of
available blocks, which block or blocks
will remain unsold—those partial or full
blocks that an incumbent wishes to
relinquish or those held by the FCC? For
example, we could attempt to minimize
payments to incumbent licensees by
first satisfying demand with FCC-held
blocks, and then, to the extent possible,
with incumbent-offered blocks. If only
some incumbent-held blocks can be
used to satisfy demand, how should we
prioritize among incumbent-held
blocks? Should we use a pseudorandom number to break such ties, or
should we prioritize blocks offered by
incumbents in a different manner, such
as allowing any incumbents with
partial-PEA spectrum usage rights to
relinquish before holders of full-PEA
rights, so as to result in a repacked
spectrum blocks that are more
consistent with the new band plan?
Alternatively, if we prioritized the
reconfiguration of the band by first
satisfying demand with incumbent-held
supply, how should we prioritize which
incumbent-held blocks to supply first?
We note that, in situations where the
demand for blocks does not exceed the
total supply of blocks, the final clock
phase price, at which incentive
payments will be calculated, is likely to
be equal to the minimum opening bid.
13. As a further encouragement for
participation in the auction, we propose
to condition bidding for new licenses in
the auction on incumbents’ offering
their existing spectrum usage rights in
the auction. In other words, an
incumbent licensee seeking new
licenses in the forward auction must be
a participant in the simultaneous
reverse auction. Such a requirement
would ensure that incumbent licensees
are not given a one-way option—
purchasing new unencumbered
2 For example, if an incumbent licensee had 150
megahertz of pre-auction spectrum throughout a
PEA before the clock auction and won bids for two
100-megahertz blocks at $10,000 a block in a PEA
where demand equaled supply at the end of the
clock auction, that licensee’s pre-auction spectrum
licenses would be cancelled, it would receive a
voucher of $15,000 (1.5 × $10,000) and it would
owe $20,000 for the two winning bids (i.e., it would
be required to pay $5,000 net).
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:07 Aug 17, 2018
Jkt 244001
spectrum at auction while keeping a
different set of blocks encumbered and
thus unavailable for an efficient auction.
14. One advantage of this approach is
it maximizes the ability of incumbent
licensees to maintain and consolidate
their holdings (or to rationalize their
holdings by relinquishing spectrum
usage rights in some areas to acquire
rights in other areas) while jointly
maximizing the amount of clear,
unencumbered spectrum for auction.
Such an incentive auction appears to be
the most efficient path forward to
rationalize the Upper 37 GHz and 39
GHz bands for mobile 5G and highspeed fixed wireless service. It promotes
a rapid transition of the currently
fragmented band while at the same time
respecting incumbent spectrum rights
and providing opportunities for entry
into the band by other wireless
providers. We seek comment on these
proposals and on alternative approaches
to conducting, in a timely manner, an
auction of licenses in the Upper 37 GHz
and 39 GHz bands. We also seek
comment on additional incentives we
could provide for incumbent licensees
to participate in the reverse auction.
15. A potential concern with the
proposed auction is that incumbents
with vouchers may have an incentive to
engage in insincere bidding in markets
where they want to be net suppliers of
spectrum to inflate the value of their
voucher payments. We seek comment
on the validity of such concerns. We
also note that these concerns should be
mitigated by our no withdrawal rule,
which we used in the forward phase of
the broadcast incentive auction. We
seek comment on any other potential
safeguards that could be implemented
against insincere bidding incentives or
other strategic behavior in the proposed
incentive auction.
16. Another potential concern is the
interaction of vouchers and bidding
credits. For example, given existing
rural and small business bidding
credits, bidders for new licenses may be
eligible to receive up to a 25 percent
credit toward their winning bid if they
qualify. If that bidding credit were
applied across their gross winning bids,
an incumbent licensee could feasibly
retain its existing holdings in the
auction while simultaneously receiving
an incentive payment.3 To avoid that
result, we propose to limit the
application of bidding credits to cash
payments for winning bids in the
3 For example, if a small business incumbent with
one 100 megahertz PEA license before the auction
won a single license in that same PEA for $10,000,
its voucher would be $10,000 while its required
payment on the one purchased license would be
$7,500 ($10,000 times 75 percent).
PO 00000
Frm 00031
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
auction, after the winning bidder has
used any vouchers it has to satisfy
winning bids. We seek comment on this
proposal and any other scenarios where
the use of an incentive auction with
vouchers may create arbitrage
opportunities given our normal bidding
rules. For example, should we address
winning bidders that default on their
payments differently here?
17. Given that non-incumbent
licensees also may qualify for bidding
credits, how should we address the
theoretical possibility that auction
proceeds could total less than the
incentive payments owed to
incumbents? Should we adopt a rule
that would preclude the auction from
closing in the event proceeds from
winning bids will be insufficient,
analogous to the final stage rule we
adopted in the broadcast television
spectrum incentive auction?
Alternatively, should we adopt a rule to
recalculate the amount of incentive
payments, so that the payments do not
exceed the available auction proceeds?
We seek comment on these potential
possibilities and how to address them.
Are there other particular scenarios in
which the auction proceeds might fall
short of the amount needed to pay the
face value of vouchers? Or other
methods of addressing such
possibilities?
18. We also seek comment on two
alternative proposals. First, incumbents
would receive license(s) for all vouchers
that are equivalent to a whole number
of new license(s) without bidding at all
in the clock phase. The specific
frequencies for these licenses would be
assigned in the assignment round.
Under this alternative, incumbent
licenses that are not encumbered would
not be able to relinquish spectrum, and
in those PEAs, the total number of
blocks offered in the clock phase would
be reduced by the number of 100
megahertz licenses held by incumbents.
In the assignment phase, all blocks won
by winning bidders and all incumbent
licenses would be assigned (or in the
case of incumbent licenses, reassigned)
frequencies.
19. A second, more narrowly tailored
alternative would be to exchange
automatically for vouchers only
encumbered PEA and RSA licenses.
Unencumbered PEA licenses would
have the option of converting their
unencumbered generic PEA blocks to
vouchers if they so choose. All
encumbered licenses would still be
required to be converted to vouchers,
since, were these licensees to hold out,
this would leave spectrum that could
not fit into the new band plan and
E:\FR\FM\20AUP1.SGM
20AUP1
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 161 / Monday, August 20, 2018 / Proposed Rules
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with PROPOSALS
thereby reduce the efficiency of the
auction.
20. Under all these approaches,
unencumbered PEA licensees can obtain
new licenses without additional license
payments. Under our proposed
approach, however, licensees would
have to bid to obtain a new license,
making more licenses available for
bidding and increasing the number of
bidders. Making unencumbered PEA
licensees bid may increase the
efficiency of the assignment of licenses
by having incumbents face the market
price of holding onto their licenses. At
a high enough price, some may
relinquish their spectrum to other
bidders who value it more highly. We
seek comment on these proposals,
particularly from any current licensee
that would choose not to participate in
the incentive auction using one of these
three approaches described above or any
other similar approach.
B. A Pre-Auction Voucher Exchange
21. To address concerns raised with
respect to incumbent licensees whose
licenses involve RSAs or encumbered
PEAs, and thus do not cover the entire
population of a PEA, we propose a preauction voucher exchange.4 Much as
vouchers in the incentive auction allow
incumbent licensees to consolidate and
rationalize their holdings during the
auction, a voucher exchange could
allow incumbents to consolidate and
rationalize their holdings before the
auction—although in a somewhat more
limited manner. Specifically, it could
aid incumbent licensees in minimizing
the number of PEAs going into the
auction in which they would have only
fractional vouchers—and thus no ability
to assure themselves that they could exit
the auction with a whole number of new
licenses without making net payments
to secure their spectrum holdings.
22. The design of the voucher
exchange should allow incumbents to
exchange their fractional vouchers in
one or more PEAs, caused by holding an
RSA or encumbered PEA license, to
create full vouchers in another PEA
subject to certain restrictions. The first
step in a voucher exchange is to
aggregate the vouchers for all
encumbered blocks within a PEA,
which is likely to leave a fractional
voucher in each PEA.
23. Next, the Commission would
specify exchange rates (expressed on a
per MHz-pop basis) that would allow
4 For encumbered PEA licenses (i.e., licenses that
are co-channel with an RSA license), the licensee’s
voucher would cover only the population where it
is authorized to operate prior to the start of the
exchange—that is, the area outside of the
overlapping RSA license.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:07 Aug 17, 2018
Jkt 244001
incumbent licensees to exchange these
fractional vouchers with the
Commission. We seek comment on how
to establish the relative exchange rates
needed for a voucher exchange. Should
we calculate those exchange rates based
on the relative value of PEA licenses
estimated from previous auctions? If so,
which prior FCC auctions should be
used to calculate the exchange rates
between PEAs?
24. Incumbents would then be
allowed to exchange their vouchers
subject to the condition that net trades
for each incumbent over all PEAs be
revenue neutral, i.e., aggregate trades up
and down will balance given the FCCspecified exchange rates.5 Vouchers
could only be exchanged up or down to
no more than the nearest integer above
or no less than the nearest integer below
their current fractional voucher
holdings.6 If there exists a PEA in which
it is not feasible for all incumbent
licensees to ‘‘trade up’’ within the 39
GHz band, we propose that incumbent
licensees would only be permitted to
‘‘trade down.’’ All voucher trades with
the Commission would be completed
prior to the clock auction phase of the
incentive auction. We propose that,
before initiating the voucher exchange,
we would educate all potential
participants so that they can understand
the process and consequences of
participating in the exchange. We find
that this should promote an efficient
process for both the Commission and
participants.
25. We seek comment on this
framework for implementing a pre5 If all of an incumbent’s licenses within PEA #1
in the aggregate cover 20% of the MHz-pops of an
unencumbered 100 megahertz block in PEA #1, the
license(s) are represented by a voucher
denominated as 0.2. If all of an incumbent’s
licenses within a PEA #2 in the aggregate cover 40
percent of the MHz-pops of an unencumbered 100
megahertz block in PEA #2, that incumbent’s
voucher in PEA #2 would be 0.4. Note that the
incumbent’s license(s) in PEA #2 might cover 80
percent of the population in the PEA with only 50
megahertz of bandwidth, or 40 percent of the
population with 100 megahertz, or 20 percent of the
population with 200 megahertz. A voucher
representing any of these combinations in PEA #2
would be denominated 0.4. If the exchange rate
between PEA #1 and #2 was such that a voucher
in PEA #2 can be exchanged for a voucher of two
times its amount in PEA #1, then the incumbent
could exchange its 0.4 voucher in PEA #2 for a PEA
#1 voucher for 0.8 (0.4 times two). The incumbent
would then combine its original 0.2 voucher in PEA
#1 with the 0.8 voucher received in the exchange
and have a 1.0 voucher in PEA #1. The incumbent’s
voucher in PEA #2 would then be 0.0.
6 Using our prior example, the limitation that
incumbents cannot increase vouchers to more than
the nearest integer above its initial holdings means
that an incumbent with 0.2 in PEA #1 and 0.9 in
PEA #2 cannot exchange its PEA #2 voucher for a
PEA #1 voucher of 1.8 (0.9 times the exchange rate
of two) because the result would increase the
incumbent’s holdings in PEA #1 from 0.2 to 2.0,
which is more than the nearest integer above, or 1.0.
PO 00000
Frm 00032
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
42093
auction voucher exchange to serve the
public interest, including how best to
address concerns raised in the record
with respect to prior proposals. To
establish the framework, we seek
comment on the best methods for
achieving our goals. How could a
voucher exchange best facilitate a low
cost rapid rationalization of spectrum
holdings by allowing incumbent
licensees to aggregate fractional
holdings across PEAs and to retain all
their equivalent spectrum usage rights
in PEAs of their choosing to the extent
permitted by their fractional holdings
and the exchange rates? Are there any
other limits or restrictions that should
be imposed on exchanges that
incumbents can make? Separate from
the voucher exchange and building on
the Voluntary Rebanding PN, should we
expand the process by which incumbent
licensees can modify their licenses prior
to the auction, for example, by allowing
for inter-market swaps using the same
exchange rates as the voucher exchange?
26. One restriction we may impose on
any exchange that will result in
modified licenses (rather than cancelled
licenses and vouchers for the auction) is
to require that any such exchange result
in less geographically encumbered
spectrum. Would that serve the public
interest? How should encumbrances be
measured? Furthermore, after
exchanging across a number of markets,
it is likely that a licensee will not be
able to have full PEA licenses in all
markets. One approach to this
remainder would be to set it to zero in
that market. Would this be appropriate,
given the opportunity afforded by the
exchanges to minimize such holdings?
What other approaches could be taken
regarding such remainders? For
example, should an incumbent be
permitted to maintain one fractional
license in one PEA?
27. We also seek comment on how the
voucher exchange should interact with
existing licenses and the incentive
auction. For example, should we cancel
or modify the affected licenses of
exchange participants before the auction
in exchange for vouchers? Should we
leave such licenses untouched until
after the auction? Should only incentive
auction participants be allowed to
participate in the voucher exchange?
Further, should we consider holding
this type of voucher exchange
independent of whether we hold an
incentive auction to allow incumbent
licensees to combine their fractional
licenses into whole licenses under the
new band plan?
E:\FR\FM\20AUP1.SGM
20AUP1
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with PROPOSALS
42094
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 161 / Monday, August 20, 2018 / Proposed Rules
C. Mandatory Repacking
28. We propose to repack incumbent
licensees that choose not to participate
in the incentive auction. Just as the
Commission repacked television
broadcasters that chose not to
participate in the broadcast incentive
auction, the Commission has the
authority to modify the holdings of
existing licensees ‘‘if in the judgment of
the Commission such action will
promote the public interest,
convenience, and necessity.’’ Repacking
the holdings of non-participating
incumbent licensees will ensure that we
can minimize encumbrances in the band
and maximize the amount of clean
spectrum available for auction, while
preserving existing usage rights for
incumbents.
29. We seek comment on all aspects
of this proposal. We also seek comment
on what criteria to apply when
repacking encumbered licenses. How
can the Commission best make modified
frequency assignments to maximize the
contiguous spectrum for auction
participants while preserving to the
greatest extent possible each incumbent
license’s bandwidth, previous
geography, and existing contiguity?
30. For example, must or should we
maintain frequency contiguity for RSA
licenses that overlap PEAs? Given the
requirement of operability throughout
the band, how significant is such
contiguity? We note that partitioning
RSAs that overlap multiple PEAs into
their respective PEAs might make it
possible to repack more efficiently and
even enable repacked frequencies to be
assigned in the auction’s assignment
phase.
31. One approach to repacking nonparticipating incumbents would involve
a two-step calculation. The first step
would entail reconfiguring those
incumbent licenses that do not align
with PEA boundaries (e.g., RSA licenses
or partial PEA licenses) into full PEA
licenses with an equivalent amount of
spectrum in each PEA, as measured in
MHz-pop. The second step would be to
restate the incumbent’s fractional
holdings of 100 MHz PEA blocks as
mostly integer numbers of 100 MHz
PEA blocks, in a way that the repacked
spectrum maintains the same value as
evaluated with respect to FCC-specified
exchange rates (i.e., those set for the
voucher exchange). In all but one of
their PEAs, the fractional holdings of a
repacked incumbent would be replaced
by either the nearest integer above or the
nearest integer below the fractional
holdings. The one PEA left with
fractional holdings would be the PEA
with the smallest possible value. We
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:07 Aug 17, 2018
Jkt 244001
note that an incumbent could avoid the
effects of such repacking by entering
into the incentive auction.
32. Other efficiencies might be
realized by other means. For example,
converting MHz-pops in a geographic
area that is less than a full PEA (i.e., an
RSA license or an encumbered PEA
license) into the same MHz-pops in a
portion of a 100 megahertz block across
the whole PEA could facilitate more
efficient repacking. We note that,
depending on how many and which
current licensees choose not to
participate in the incentive auction,
there may be some left-over segments,
i.e., when less than a whole 100
megahertz PEA block remains. We seek
comment on whether we should attempt
to consolidate such holdout segments in
this manner, and if so whether to
auction overlay licenses on them or
otherwise maximize their value for the
American public.
33. We seek comment on the options
presented above, including possible
variations, and on the costs and benefits
of mandatory repacking for nonparticipants. Should there be a de
minimis spectrum holdings threshold to
qualify for repacking and how should
this level be set? How and when should
the frequency reassignment be done in
order to minimize the spectrum
required to repack holdout licenses?
How should the adjacent spectrum
blocks to the holdout segment be
auctioned, given that they may be less
than 100 megahertz?
D. Incentive Auction Legal Authority
34. Congress expressly authorized the
Commission to conduct incentive
auctions beyond the broadcast
television spectrum incentive auction.
Using this authority, the Commission
can offer incentive payments to
licensees that choose to relinquish
existing spectrum usage rights provided
by incumbent licenses instead of
retaining such rights pursuant to new
licenses. More specifically, the
‘‘Commission may encourage a licensee
to relinquish voluntarily some or all of
its licensed spectrum usage rights in
order to permit the assignment of new
initial licenses subject to flexible-use
service rules by sharing with such
licensee a portion . . . of the proceeds
(including deposits and upfront
payments from successful bidders) from
the use of a competitive bidding system
under this subsection.’’ To do so, the
Commission must determine ‘‘the value
of the relinquished rights . . . in the
reverse auction’’ and that reverse
auction must have ‘‘at least two
competing licensees participate.’’
PO 00000
Frm 00033
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
35. As explained above, we propose to
use the clock phase winning bids for
new licenses to determine the incentive
payment that participating incumbent
licensees may receive. A participating
incumbent licensee will have a choice
between competing in bidding for new
licenses and offering spectrum usage
rights or relinquishing spectrum usage
rights under existing licenses in
exchange for an incentive payment.
36. Under the auction design
proposed above, any relinquishment of
spectrum usage rights for an incentive
payment would be ‘‘voluntary’’ within
the meaning of the statute. All
incumbent licensees may decline to
participate in the incentive auction and
instead receive new licenses that
provide spectrum usage rights
equivalent to their existing licenses.
Modifying existing licenses in this way
does not, however, require the use of
our incentive auction authority. Rather,
we rely on our clear authority to modify
license frequencies pursuant to the
public interest. Given that incumbent
licensees will participate in the
incentive auction by choice, we
conclude that any subsequent decision
an incumbent doing so makes to
relinquish spectrum usage rights should
be considered voluntary. We seek
comment on our conclusion.
37. We propose above that incumbent
licensees that choose not to participate
in the reverse auction may not
participate in the auction of new
licenses. Could that additional
consequence of choosing not to
participate affect whether a subsequent
relinquishment is voluntary? An
incumbent licensee that chooses
between relinquishing spectrum usage
rights for an incentive payment or
instead receiving new licenses for
equivalent spectrum usage rights at no
additional cost presumably does so
voluntarily, regardless of whether it
chose to participate because of some
collateral consequence of nonparticipation. Nothing compels such a
licensee to make the relinquishment
instead of retaining its spectrum usage
rights under new licenses.
38. We also conclude that our
proposal that incumbent licensees that
choose not to participate in the reverse
auction may not participate in the
forward auction of new licenses is
consistent with our authority to
determine qualifications that auction
participants must satisfy. More
specifically, we conclude that the
proposed consequence of an
incumbent’s choice would constitute a
rule of general applicability regarding
auction participation. We seek comment
on these conclusions.
E:\FR\FM\20AUP1.SGM
20AUP1
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 161 / Monday, August 20, 2018 / Proposed Rules
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with PROPOSALS
39. Our proposal satisfies additional
statutory requirements for our incentive
auction authority. The ‘‘reverse’’ nature
of the auction required by the statute is
one in which those rights are
relinquished by licensees to the
Commission, reversing the typical flow
of rights assigned based on spectrum
license auctions. Although auctions in
other contexts—such as the Connect
America Fund Phase II Auction to
distribute universal service support for
high-speed broadband deployment in
rural America—are sometimes called
reverse auctions because the price
declines over the course of bidding,
nothing in the statute requires that a
reverse auction to relinquish spectrum
usage rights use descending bidding. We
note that in the broadcast television
spectrum incentive auction, the
Commission chose to use a descending
clock price auction for the reverse
auction component because a
descending clock auction design
involved several features that were
particularly helpful in that context, not
because it was statutorily required.
40. We also conclude that, so long as
at least two incumbent licensees with
licenses in the same PEA choose to
participate in the incentive auction, the
reverse auction will meet the statutory
requirement to have at least ‘‘two
competing licensees participat[ing]’’ in
the reverse auction.7 In the broadcast
television spectrum incentive auction,
the Commission concluded that at least
two licensees participate in the reverse
auction so long as more than one noncommonly controlled party qualifies as
an applicant to participate in the
auction. This is so because any qualified
applicant that bids in the auction must
take into account the presence of
another qualified applicant that has the
opportunity to bid, regardless of
whether the second applicant in fact
bids. We find that same conclusion
should apply here, too. Incumbents
seeking to relinquish spectrum usage
rights in the proposed auction must take
into account the demand for new
licenses by other qualified applicants, as
they only will be able to relinquish
rights so long as demand for new
licenses exceeds supply. We seek
comment on this analysis.
41. Further, we seek comment
generally on whether our proposal to
7 See Incentive Auction Report and Order, 29 FCC
Rcd at 6742, para. 413. The Commission took care
to note that it might ‘‘apply [the two competing
participants] requirement differently in other
reverse auctions, depending upon the particular
eligibility criteria, auction design and other
circumstances.’’ Id. at 6743, para. 414 n.1224.
Accordingly, while we find the discussion
regarding this requirement helpful, it is not
controlling.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:07 Aug 17, 2018
Jkt 244001
conduct an auction with the elements
described above or any of our
alternative scenarios for conducting an
incentive auction would be consistent
with our statutory authority to conduct
an incentive auction. To the extent that
commenters assert that these scenarios
are not consistent with our incentive
auction authority, commenters should
discuss any changes that could more
fully satisfy that authority.
42. As noted above in our proposal,
we have authority to modify the
holdings of existing licensees based on
our judgment of the public interest. We
conclude that the potential
modifications considered above are
within our authority. We ask that
commenters proposing further
modifications to address whether their
proposals are within our authority.
43. Legal Authority for Alternative
Auction Mechanisms. We seek comment
on alternative legal authority should we
decide not to conduct an incentive
auction. For example, we seek comment
on whether we might conduct an
auction as described above while
providing current licensees with
bidding offset credits in place of
vouchers and incentive payments. We
seek comment on whether issuing
bidding offset credits in order to protect
existing spectrum uses—and past
Commission public interest judgments
reflected in prior licensing decisions—
while clearing existing spectrum
assignments is necessary to the
management of spectrum in the public
interest and not inconsistent with the
Communications Act. Effectively
clearing prior spectrum assignments so
that new licenses for this spectrum may
be assigned by competitive bidding will
promote statutory objectives. Issuing
bidding offset credits is within the
Commission’s statutory authority
regarding the design of competitive
bidding systems. Section 309(j)(4) of the
Communications Act grants the
Commission authority to consider a
variety of methods of helping entities
pay for licenses that are offered at
auction, including alternative payment
schedules, tax credits, and bidding
preferences.
44. We ask commenters to address the
differences, if any, in incentives
provided to current licensees by
providing them with a bidding offset
credit without an opportunity to receive
an incentive payment. Commenters
should address the likely differences in
the outcome of the auction resulting
from such different incentives, and
whether providing incentive payments
would better serve the public interest,
notwithstanding the need to share a
portion of the auction proceeds. Would
PO 00000
Frm 00034
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
42095
the amount of repurposed spectrum be
affected? We also seek comment on any
other approaches that might achieve the
purposes of the proposal without
sharing proceeds from the auction of
new licenses with existing licensees.
III. Initial Regulatory Flexibility
Analysis
45. As required by the Regulatory
Flexibility Act of 1980, as amended
(RFA), the Commission has prepared
this present Initial Regulatory
Flexibility Analysis (IRFA) of the
possible significant economic impact on
a substantial number of small entities by
the policies and rules proposed in the
attached 4th FNPRM . Written public
comments are requested on this IRFA.
Comments must be identified as
responses to the IRFA and must be filed
by the deadlines for comments as
specified in the 4th FNPRM. The
Commission will send a copy of this 4th
FNPRM, including this IRFA, to the
Chief Counsel for Advocacy of the Small
Business Administration (SBA). In
addition, the 4th FNPRM and IRFA (or
summaries thereof) will be published in
the Federal Register.
A. Need for, and Objectives of, the
Proposed Rules
46. In the 4th FNPRM, we propose to
modify the band plan for the 38.6–40
GHz (39 GHz) band to 100 megahertz
channels for the Part 30 Upper
Microwave Flexible Use Service
(UMFUS), and propose to similarly
modify the 37.6–38.6 GHz (Upper 37
GHz) and 47.2–48.2 GHz (47 GHz) bands
to 100 megahertz channels if we adopt
the 100 megahertz channel plan for the
39 GHz band. The 4th FNPRM also
seeks comment on which auction
mechanism to use to realign existing 39
GHz licenses.
47. First, we propose to modify the 39
GHz band plan from seven 200
megahertz to fourteen 100 megahertz
channels to allow for better
consolidation of existing license
holdings. We propose modifying the
Upper 37 GHz band plan from 200
megahertz to 100 megahertz channels,
given that the two bands are adjacent
and have the same service rules and an
operability requirement. Further, in the
4th FNPRM we propose to auction the
39 GHz and Upper 37 bands together. In
addition we propose to modify the 47
GHz band plan from 200 to 100
megahertz channels if we auction all
three bands at the same time and seek
comment on that proposal.
48. Second, we propose to use a twophase incentive auction. In the first
phase, participants would bid to win
generic spectrum blocks using an
E:\FR\FM\20AUP1.SGM
20AUP1
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with PROPOSALS
42096
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 161 / Monday, August 20, 2018 / Proposed Rules
ascending clock auction that would
determine a uniform price in each
PEA—this encompasses the
simultaneous forward-and-reverse
auction. The second phase would assign
specific-frequency licenses by PEA that
would aim to ensure contiguity within
each PEA. Because the spectrum blocks
in the Upper 37 GHz and 39 GHz bands
can be treated as largely interchangeable
within a PEA, we propose to offer
unencumbered blocks as one category of
generic blocks in a clock auction.
Specifically, we propose to use a clock
auction design with rules similar to
those used for the forward auction in
the broadcast incentive auction and the
planned 24 GHz auction. Next, winning
bidders from the clock phase would
have an opportunity to submit sealed
bids by PEA for particular frequency
blocks in a separate assignment phase.
We propose that this assignment phase
be voluntary: Winning bidders need not
bid in the assignment phase. Regardless
of its participation in the assignment
phase, the assignment phase would aim
to assign contiguous frequency blocks
within a PEA to a bidder that wins
multiple blocks.
49. We propose to encourage
incumbent licensees to participate in
the reverse auction by offering them an
incentive payment—using what we term
here a ‘‘voucher’’—in exchange for the
cancellation of certain incumbent
licenses at the end of the auction. Each
voucher would have a dollar value
equal to the final clock phase price (for
a single generic block under the new
band plan) in the PEA in which the
incumbent license is located times the
ratio of bandwidth provided by the
incumbent’s license and the population
that can be reached using that license
within a given PEA (expressed in MHzpops) divided by the bandwidth and
population reached by a generic block
(expressed in MHz-pops). We propose to
further encourage incumbent licensees
to participate in the reverse auction by
requiring such participation if the
incumbent licensee seeks to participate
in the accompanying forward auction.
In addition, we seek comment on two
alternative auction proposals. First,
incumbents would receive license(s) for
all vouchers that are equivalent to a
whole number of new license(s) without
bidding at all in the clock phase. In the
assignment phase, all blocks won by
winning bidders and all incumbent
licenses would be assigned (or in the
case of incumbent licenses, reassigned)
frequencies. We seek comment on a
second alternative in which we would
exchange automatically for vouchers
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:07 Aug 17, 2018
Jkt 244001
only encumbered PEA and RSA
licenses.
50. Third, we propose a pre-auction
voucher exchange process in which
incumbents can trade fractional license
holdings for full license holdings—
including across markets in some
circumstances—under the new band
plan, with these trades reflected as full
vouchers in the auction. The exchange
would allow incumbents to aggregate
fractional holdings across PEAs and to
retain all their equivalent spectrum
usage rights in PEAs of their choosing
to the extent permitted by their
fractional holdings and the exchange
rates. We seek comment on establishing
the relative exchange rates needed for a
voucher exchange. We seek comment on
a framework for implementing a preauction voucher exchange to serve the
public interest, including how best to
address concerns raised in the record
with respect to prior proposals.
51. Fourth, we propose to repack
incumbent licensees that choose not to
participate in reverse auction portion of
the incentive auction. Repacking the
holdings of non-participating incumbent
licensees will ensure that we can
minimize encumbrances in the band,
maximizing the amount of clean
spectrum available for auction, while
preserving existing usage rights for
incumbents. We propose that licensees
that choose to repack encumbered
licenses in lieu of exchanging for
vouchers should not be allowed to bid
on new licenses in either the clock
phase of the auction or be allowed to
bid on frequency assignments during
the assignment round. Prohibiting
auction participation for such licensees
would create a strong incentive for
incumbents to choose to exchange all of
their licenses for vouchers.
52. Lastly, we propose to auction
together all licenses in the Upper 37
GHz and 39 GHz, using the
Commission’s incentive auction
authority, where existing 39 GHz license
holders could relinquish their spectrum
usage rights in return for an incentive
payment, and/or acquire new rights. We
conclude that the auction design we
propose would satisfy the requirement
to conduct a reverse auction to
determine the amount of compensation
licensees would accept for voluntarily
relinquishing spectrum usage rights. All
incumbent licensees may decline to
participate in the incentive auction and
instead receive new licenses that
provide spectrum usage rights
equivalent to their existing licenses. We
seek comment on our proposal to
condition bidding for new licenses in
the auction on incumbents’ offering
their existing spectrum usage rights in
PO 00000
Frm 00035
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
the auction. Such a requirement would
ensure that incumbent licensees are not
given a one-way option—purchasing
new unencumbered spectrum at auction
while keeping a different set of blocks
encumbered and thus unavailable for an
efficient auction. Furthermore, in case
we were to conclude that the auction
design proposed above would not
satisfy the statutory requirements for an
incentive auction, we seek comment on
alternatives in which auction proceeds
are not shared with incumbents, such as
providing current licensees with
bidding offset credits in place of
vouchers
53. Overall, the proposals in the 4th
FNPRM are designed to facilitate
broadband deployment, including 5G
services, by providing opportunities to
make it easier for licensees in the band
to rationalize their existing holdings
into contiguous swathes of spectrum,
and by offering new licenses of
contiguous spectrum at auction while
protecting incumbents’ existing
spectrum usage rights. This will ensure
that this spectrum is efficiently used
and will foster the development of new
and innovative technologies and
services, as well as encourage the
growth and development of a wide
variety of services, ultimately leading to
greater benefits to consumers.
B. Legal Basis
54. The proposed action is authorized
pursuant to Sections 1, 2, 3, 4, 5, 7, 301,
302, 302a, 303, 304, 307, 309, and 310
of the Communications Act of 1934, as
amended, 47 U.S.C. 151, 152, 153, 154,
155, 157, 301, 302, 302a, 303, 304, 307,
309, and 310, Section 706 of the
Telecommunications Act of 1996, as
amended, 47 U.S.C. 1302.
C. Description and Estimate of the
Number of Small Entities to Which the
Proposed Rules Will Apply
55. The RFA directs agencies to
provide a description of and, where
feasible, an estimate of the number of
small entities that may be affected by
the proposed rules, if adopted. The RFA
generally defines the term ‘‘small
entity’’ as having the same meaning as
the terms ‘‘small business,’’ ‘‘small
organization,’’ and ‘‘small governmental
jurisdiction.’’ In addition, the term
‘‘small business’’ has the same meaning
as the term ‘‘small business concern’’
under the Small Business Act.’’ A
‘‘small business concern’’ is one which:
(1) Is independently owned and
operated; (2) is not dominant in its field
of operation; and (3) satisfies any
additional criteria established by the
SBA.
E:\FR\FM\20AUP1.SGM
20AUP1
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with PROPOSALS
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 161 / Monday, August 20, 2018 / Proposed Rules
56. Small Businesses, Small
Organizations, Small Governmental
Jurisdictions. Our actions, over time,
may affect small entities that are not
easily categorized at present. We
therefore describe here, at the outset,
three broad groups of small entities that
could be directly affected herein. First,
while there are industry specific size
standards for small businesses that are
used in the regulatory flexibility
analysis, according to data from the
SBA’s Office of Advocacy, in general a
small business is an independent
business having fewer than 500
employees. These types of small
businesses represent 99.9% of all
businesses in the United States which
translates to 28.8 million businesses.
57. Next, the type of small entity
described as a ‘‘small organization’’ is
generally ‘‘any not-for-profit enterprise
which is independently owned and
operated and is not dominant in its
field.’’ Nationwide, as of August 2016,
there were approximately 356,494 small
organizations based on registration and
tax data filed by nonprofits with the
Internal Revenue Service (IRS).
58. Finally, the small entity described
as a ‘‘small governmental jurisdiction’’
is defined generally as ‘‘governments of
cities, counties, towns, townships,
villages, school districts, or special
districts, with a population of less than
fifty thousand.’’ U.S. Census Bureau
data from the 2012 Census of
Governments indicate that there were
90,056 local governmental jurisdictions
consisting of general purpose
governments and special purpose
governments in the United States. Of
this number there were 37,132 General
purpose governments (county,
municipal and town or township) with
populations of less than 50,000 and
12,184 Special purpose governments
(independent school districts and
special districts) with populations of
less than 50,000. The 2012 U.S. Census
Bureau data for most types of
governments in the local government
category show that the majority of these
governments have populations of less
than 50,000. Based on this data we
estimate that at least 49,316 local
government jurisdictions fall in the
category of ‘‘small governmental
jurisdictions.’’
59. Wireless Telecommunications
Carriers (except Satellite). This industry
comprises establishments engaged in
operating and maintaining switching
and transmission facilities to provide
communications via the airwaves.
Establishments in this industry have
spectrum licenses and provide services
using that spectrum, such as cellular
services, paging services, wireless
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:07 Aug 17, 2018
Jkt 244001
internet access, and wireless video
services. The appropriate size standard
under SBA rules is that such a business
is small if it has 1,500 or fewer
employees. For this industry, U.S.
Census Bureau data for 2012 show that
there were 967 firms that operated for
the entire year. Of this total, 955 firms
had employment of 999 or fewer
employees and 12 had employment of
1,000 employees or more. Thus under
this category and the associated size
standard, the Commission estimates that
the majority of wireless
telecommunications carriers (except
satellite) are small entities.
60. Fixed Microwave Services.
Microwave services include common
carrier, private-operational fixed, and
broadcast auxiliary radio services. They
also include the Upper Microwave
Flexible Use Service, the Millimeter
Wave Service, Local Multipoint
Distribution Service (LMDS), the Digital
Electronic Message Service (DEMS), and
the 24 GHz Service, where licensees can
choose between common carrier and
non-common carrier status. At present,
there are approximately 66,680 common
carrier fixed licensees, 69,360 private
and public safety operational-fixed
licensees, 20,150 broadcast auxiliary
radio licensees, 411 LMDS licenses, 33
24 GHz DEMS licenses, 777 39 GHz
licenses, and five 24 GHz licensees, and
467 Millimeter Wave licenses in the
microwave services. The Commission
has not yet defined a small business
with respect to microwave services. The
closest applicable SBA category is
Wireless Telecommunications Carriers
(except Satellite) and the appropriate
size standard for this category under
SBA rules is that such a business is
small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees.
For this industry, U.S. Census Bureau
data for 2012 shows that there were 967
firms that operated for the entire year.
Of this total, 955 had employment of
999 or fewer, and 12 firms had
employment of 1,000 employees or
more. Thus under this SBA category and
the associated standard, the
Commission estimates that the majority
of fixed microwave service licensees can
be considered small.
61. The Commission does not have
data specifying the number of these
licensees that have more than 1,500
employees, and thus is unable at this
time to estimate with greater precision
the number of fixed microwave service
licensees that would qualify as small
business concerns under the SBA’s
small business size standard.
Consequently, the Commission
estimates that there are up to 36,708
common carrier fixed licensees and up
to 59,291 private operational-fixed
PO 00000
Frm 00036
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
42097
licensees and broadcast auxiliary radio
licensees in the microwave services that
may be small and may be affected by the
rules and policies proposed herein. We
note, however, that both the common
carrier microwave fixed and the private
operational microwave fixed licensee
categories includes some large entities.
62. All Other Telecommunications.
The ‘‘All Other Telecommunications’’
category is comprised of establishments
primarily engaged in providing
specialized telecommunications
services, such as satellite tracking,
communications telemetry, and radar
station operation. This industry also
includes establishments primarily
engaged in providing satellite terminal
stations and associated facilities
connected with one or more terrestrial
systems and capable of transmitting
telecommunications to, and receiving
telecommunications from, satellite
systems. Establishments providing
internet services or voice over internet
protocol (VoIP) services via clientsupplied telecommunications
connections are also included in this
industry.’’ The SBA has developed a
small business size standard for ‘‘All
Other Telecommunications,’’ which
consists of all such firms with gross
annual receipts of $32.5 million or less.
For this category, U.S. Census Bureau
data for 2012 shows that there were a
total of 1,442 firms that operated for the
entire year. Of these firms, a total of
1400 firms had gross annual receipts of
under $25 million and 42 firms had
gross annual receipts of $25 million to
$49,999,999. Thus, the Commission
estimates that a majority of ‘‘All Other
Telecommunications’’ firms potentially
affected by our actions can be
considered small.
63. Radio and Television
Broadcasting and Wireless
Communications Equipment
Manufacturing. This industry comprises
establishments primarily engaged in
manufacturing radio and television
broadcast and wireless communications
equipment. Examples of products made
by these establishments are:
Transmitting and receiving antennas,
cable television equipment, GPS
equipment, pagers, cellular phones,
mobile communications equipment, and
radio and television studio and
broadcasting equipment.’’ The SBA has
established a size standard for this
industry of 1,250 employees or less.
U.S. Census Bureau data for 2012 shows
that 841 establishments operated in this
industry in that year. Of that number,
828 establishments operated with fewer
than 1,000 employees, 7 establishments
operated with between 1,000 and 2,499
employees and 6 establishments
E:\FR\FM\20AUP1.SGM
20AUP1
42098
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 161 / Monday, August 20, 2018 / Proposed Rules
operated with 2,500 or more employees.
Based on this data, we conclude that a
majority of manufacturers in this
industry is small.
D. Description of Projected Reporting,
Recordkeeping, and Other Compliance
Requirements
64. We expect the rules and
procedures proposed in the 4th FNPRM
will impose new or additional reporting
or recordkeeping and/or other
compliance obligations on small entities
as well as other licensees with licenses
in the 39 GHz band issued prior to the
auction of new licenses proposed in the
4th FNPRM. The proposed rules and
procedures would require parties with
licenses in the 39 GHz band issued prior
to the auction of new licenses proposed
in the 4th FNPRM to provide certain
information following the auction of the
new licenses. Depending upon the
licensee’s individual circumstances, the
information required may include
directions regarding the cancellation of
pre-existing licenses, directions
regarding a choice between satisfying
winning bids for new licenses and
receiving incentive payments, and
directions regarding how any incentive
payments are to be made.
65. The projected reporting,
recordkeeping, and other compliance
requirements resulting from this
proceeding would apply to all such
licensees in the same manner. The
Commission believes that applying the
same rules equally to all entities in this
context would promote fairness. We
note that eight of the existing fourteen
such licensees may be considered small
entities. The Commission does not
believe that the costs and/or
administrative burdens associated with
the rules would unduly burden small
entities. Moreover, the proposed reverse
auction would benefit any affected
small entities by providing an
opportunity to receive an incentive
payment in exchange for spectrum
usage rights.
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with PROPOSALS
E. Steps Taken To Minimize Significant
Economic Impact on Small Entities, and
Significant Alternatives Considered
66. The RFA requires an agency to
describe any significant alternatives for
small businesses that it has considered
in reaching its proposed approach,
which may include the following four
alternatives (among others): (1) The
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:07 Aug 17, 2018
Jkt 244001
establishment of differing compliance or
reporting requirements or timetables
that take into account the resources
available to small entities; (2) the
clarification, consolidation, or
simplification of compliance and
reporting requirements under the rule
for such small entities; (3) the use of
performance rather than design
standards; and (4) an exemption from
coverage of the rule, or any part thereof,
for such small entities.
67. The Commission does not believe
that its proposed changes will have a
significant economic impact on small
entities. We believe that modifying the
band plan from 200 megahertz to 100
megahertz channels in the 39 GHz,
Upper 37 GHz, and 47 GHz bands will
help small entities by making spectrum
available in smaller license sizes that
may be more attractive to small entities.
We also believe the proposed
mechanism for auctioning the 39 GHz
and Upper 37 GHz bands would
facilitate access to spectrum by small
businesses and a wide variety of other
entities, while preserving incumbent
licensees’ spectrum rights. However, to
get a better understanding of costs and
any burdens, we seek comment on
whether any of the burdens associated
with the proposed rules and policies
can be minimized for small businesses.
The Commission expects to more fully
consider the economic impact and
alternatives for small entities following
the review of comments filed in
response to the 4th FNPRM.
F. Federal Rules That May Duplicate,
Overlap, or Conflict With the Proposed
Rules
68. None.
IV. Ordering Clauses
69. It is ordered, pursuant to the
authority found in Sections 1, 2, 3, 4, 5,
7, 301, 302, 303, 304, 307, 309, 310, and
316 of the Communications Act of 1934,
47 U.S.C. 151, 152, 153, 154, 155, 157,
301, 302, 303, 304, 307, 309, 310, and
316, and § 1.411 of the Commission’s
Rules, 47 CFR 1.411, that this 4th
FNPRM is hereby adopted.
70. It is further ordered that the
Commission’s Consumer and
Governmental Affairs Bureau, Reference
Information Center, shall send a copy of
this 4th FNPRM, including the Initial
Regulatory Flexibility Analysis, to the
Chief Counsel for Advocacy of the Small
Business Administration.
PO 00000
Frm 00037
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
List of Subjects in 47 CFR Part 30
Communications common carriers,
Reporting and recordkeeping
requirements, Communications
equipment.
Federal Communications Commission.
Katura Jackson,
Federal Register Liaison Officer, Office of the
Secretary.
Proposed Rules
For the reasons discussed in the
preamble, the Federal Communications
Commission proposes to amend 47 CFR
part 30 as follows:
PART 30—UPPER MICROWAVE
FLEXIBLE USE SERVICE
1. The authority citation for part 30
continues to read as follows:
■
Authority: 47 U.S.C. 151, 152, 153, 154,
301, 303, 304, 307, 309, 310, 316, 332, 1302.
2. Amend § 30.4 by:
a. Redesignating paragraphs (b)
through (e) as paragraphs (c), (d), (f),
and (g);
■ b. Adding and reserving new
paragraphs (b) and (e); and
■ c. Revising redesignated paragraphs
(d)(1), (f), and (g).
The revisions and addition read as
follows:
■
■
§ 30.4
Frequencies.
*
*
*
*
*
(b) [Reserved]
*
*
*
*
*
(d) * * *
(1) New channel plan:
Frequency
band limits
(MHz)
Channel No.
1 ......................................
2 ......................................
3 ......................................
4 ......................................
5 ......................................
6 ......................................
7 ......................................
8 ......................................
9 ......................................
10 ....................................
11 ....................................
12 ....................................
13 ....................................
14 ....................................
*
E:\FR\FM\20AUP1.SGM
*
*
20AUP1
*
*
38,600–38,700
38,700–38,800
38,800–38,900
38,900–39,000
39,000–39,100
39,100–39,200
39,200–39,300
39,300–39,400
39,400–39,500
39,500–39,600
39,600–39,700
39,700–39,800
39,800–39,900
39,900–40,000
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 161 / Monday, August 20, 2018 / Proposed Rules
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with PROPOSALS
(e) [Reserved]
(f) 37–38.6 GHz band: 37,600–37,700;
37,700–37,800 MHz; 37,800–37,900
MHz; 37,900–38,000 MHz; 38,000–
38,100 MHz; 38,100–38,200 MHz;
38,200–38,300 MHz; 38,300–38,400
MHz; 38,400–38,500 MHz, and 38,500–
VerDate Sep<11>2014
18:07 Aug 17, 2018
Jkt 244001
38,600 MHz. The 37,000–37,600 MHz
band segment shall be available on a
site-specific, coordinated shared basis
with eligible Federal entities.
(g) 47.2–48.2 GHz band—47.2–47.3
GHz; 47.3–47.4 GHz; 47.4–47.5 GHz;
47.5–47.6 GHz; 47.6–47.7 GHz; 47.7–
PO 00000
Frm 00038
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 9990
42099
47.8 GHz; 47.8–47.9 GHz; 47.9–48.0
GHz; 48.0–48.1 GHz; and 48.1–48.2
GHz.
[FR Doc. 2018–17820 Filed 8–17–18; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6712–01–P
E:\FR\FM\20AUP1.SGM
20AUP1
Agencies
[Federal Register Volume 83, Number 161 (Monday, August 20, 2018)]
[Proposed Rules]
[Pages 42089-42099]
From the Federal Register Online via the Government Publishing Office [www.gpo.gov]
[FR Doc No: 2018-17820]
=======================================================================
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION
47 CFR Part 30
[GN Docket No. 14-177; FCC 18-110]
Use of Spectrum Bands Above 24 GHz for Mobile Radio Services
AGENCY: Federal Communications Commission.
ACTION: Proposed rule.
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
SUMMARY: In this document, a Fourth Notice of Proposed Rulemaking (4th
FNPRM) invites members of the public to comment on how best to
transition existing spectrum holdings in the 39 GHz band to the new
flexible-use band plan, and on using an incentive auction mechanism.
The Federal Communications Commission (Commission or FCC) proposes to
modify the 39 GHz, Upper 37 GHz, and 47 GHz band plans from 200
megahertz to 100 megahertz channels to facilitate the auctioning of all
three bands at the same time. The Commission also proposes an incentive
auction to reduce encumbrances and create contiguous blocks of spectrum
through the 39 GHz and Upper 37 GHz bands. These proposals will promote
the efficient use of this spectrum by incumbents and new licensees.
DATES: Comments are due on or before September 17, 2018, and reply
comments are due on or before October 8, 2018.
ADDRESSES: You may submit comments, identified by GN Docket No. 14-177,
by any of the following methods:
Federal eRulemaking Portal: https://www.regulations.gov.
Follow the instructions for submitting comments.
Federal Communications Commission's website: https://www.fcc.gov/ecfs/. Follow the instructions for submitting comments.
People with Disabilities: Contact the FCC to request
reasonable accommodations (accessible format documents, sign language
interpreters, CART, etc.) by email: [email protected], phone: 202-418-0530
or TTY: 202-418-0432.
For detailed instructions for submitting comments and additional
information on the rulemaking process, see the SUPPLEMENTARY
INFORMATION section of this document.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: Erik Salovaara, Wireless
Telecommunications Bureau, Auctions and Spectrum Access Division, (202)
418-0660, [email protected] or Simon Banyai, Wireless
Telecommunications Bureau, Broadband Division, (202) 418-1443,
[email protected].
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: This is a summary of the Commission's 4th
Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking (4th FNPRM), GN Docket No. 14-
177, FCC 18-110, adopted on August 2, 2018, and released on August 3,
2018. The complete text of this document is available for public
inspection and copying from 8 a.m. to 4:30 p.m. Eastern Time (ET)
Monday through Thursday or from 8 a.m. to 11:30 a.m. ET on Fridays in
the FCC Reference Information Center, 445 12th Street SW, Room CY-A257,
Washington, DC 20554. The complete text is also available on the
Commission's website at https://wireless.fcc.gov, or by using the search
function on the ECFS web page at https://www.fcc.gov/cgb/ecfs/.
Alternative formats are available to persons with disabilities by
sending an email to [email protected] or by calling the Consumer &
Governmental Affairs Bureau at (202) 418-0530 (voice), (202) 418-0432
(tty).
Comment Filing Procedures
Pursuant to Sec. Sec. 1.415 and 1.419 of the Commission's rules,
47 CFR 1.415, 1.419, interested parties may file comments and reply
comments on or before the dates indicated on the first page of this
document. Comments may be filed using the Commission's Electronic
Comment Filing System (ECFS). See Electronic Filing of Documents in
Rulemaking Proceedings, 63 FR 24121 (1998).
Electronic Filers: Comments may be filed electronically
using the internet by accessing the ECFS: https://www.fcc.gov/ecfs/filings. Filers should follow the instructions provided on the website
for submitting comments. In completing the transmittal screen, filers
should include their full name, U.S. Postal Service mailing address,
and the applicable docket number, GN Docket No. 14-177.
Paper Filers: Parties who choose to file by paper must
file an original and one copy of each filing. If more than one docket
or rulemaking number appears in the caption of this proceeding, filers
must submit two additional copies for
[[Page 42090]]
each additional docket or rulemaking number.
Filings can be sent by hand or messenger delivery, by commercial
overnight courier, or by first-class or overnight U.S. Postal Service
mail. All filings must be addressed to the Commission's Secretary,
Office of the Secretary, Federal Communications Commission.
All hand-delivered or messenger-delivered paper filings
for the Commission's Secretary must be delivered to FCC Headquarters at
445 12th St. SW, Room TW-A325, Washington, DC 20554. The filing hours
are 8:00 a.m. to 7:00 p.m. All hand deliveries must be held together
with rubber bands or fasteners. Any envelopes and boxes must be
disposed of before entering the building.
Commercial overnight mail (other than U.S. Postal Service
Express Mail and Priority Mail) must be sent to 9050 Junction Dr.,
Annapolis Junction, Annapolis, MD 20701.
U.S. Postal Service first-class, Express, and Priority
mail must be addressed to 445 12th Street SW, Washington, DC 20554.
People with Disabilities: To request materials in accessible
formats for people with disabilities (braille, large print, electronic
files, audio format), send an email to [email protected] or call the
Consumer & Governmental Affairs Bureau at 202-418-0530 (voice), 888-
835-5322 (tty).
Ex Parte Rules--Permit-But-Disclose
Pursuant to Sec. 1.1200(a) of the Commission's rules, this 4th
FNPRM shall be treated as a ``permit-but-disclose'' proceeding in
accordance with the Commission's ex parte rules. Persons making ex
parte presentations must file a copy of any written presentation or a
memorandum summarizing any oral presentation within two business days
after the presentation (unless a different deadline applicable to the
Sunshine period applies). Persons making oral ex parte presentations
are reminded that memoranda summarizing the presentation must (1) list
all persons attending or otherwise participating in the meeting at
which the ex parte presentation was made, and (2) summarize all data
presented and arguments made during the presentation. If the
presentation consisted in whole or in part of the presentation of data
or arguments already reflected in the presenter's written comments,
memoranda or other filings in the proceeding, the presenter may provide
citations to such data or arguments in his or her prior comments,
memoranda, or other filings (specifying the relevant page and/or
paragraph numbers where such data or arguments can be found) in lieu of
summarizing them in the memorandum. Documents shown or given to
Commission staff during ex parte meetings are deemed to be written ex
parte presentations and must be filed consistent with Sec. 1.1206(b).
In proceedings governed by Sec. 1.49(f) or for which the Commission
has made available a method of electronic filing, written ex parte
presentations and memoranda summarizing oral ex parte presentations,
and all attachments thereto, must be filed through the electronic
comment filing system available for that proceeding, and must be filed
in their native format (e.g., .doc, .xml, .ppt, searchable .pdf).
Participants in this proceeding should familiarize themselves with the
Commission's ex parte rules.
Initial Regulatory Flexibility Analysis
As required by the Regulatory Flexibility Act of 1980, as amended
(RFA), the Commission has prepared this present Initial Regulatory
Flexibility Analysis (IRFA) of the possible significant economic impact
on a substantial number of small entities by the policies and rules
proposed in the attached 4th FNPRM. Written public comments are
requested on this IRFA. Comments must be identified as responses to the
IRFA and must be filed by the deadlines for comments as specified in
the 4th FNPRM. The Commission will send a copy of this 4th FNPRM,
including this IRFA, to the Chief Counsel for Advocacy of the Small
Business Administration (SBA). In addition, the 4th FNPRM and IRFA (or
summaries thereof) will be published in the Federal Register.
Paperwork Reduction Act
The 4th FNPRM seeks comment on potential new or revised information
collection requirements. If the Commission adopts any new or revised
information collection requirements, the Commission will publish a
notice in the Federal Register inviting the public to comment on the
requirements, as required by the Paperwork Reduction Act of 1995,
Public Law 104-13 (44 U.S.C. 3501-3520). In addition, pursuant to the
Small Business Paperwork Relief Act of 2002, Public Law 107-198, see 44
U.S.C. 3506(c)(4), the Commission seeks specific comment on how it
might ``further reduce the information collection burden for small
business concerns with fewer than 25 employees.''
Synopsis
I. Band Plan
1. We propose to modify the 39 GHz band plan from seven 200
megahertz channels to fourteen 100 megahertz channels. This change
should better accommodate the repacking of incumbents, which in the
vast majority of cases, hold two non-contiguous 50 megahertz license
blocks for each original paired license (now unpaired). Given the
natural fit between incumbents' existing 100 megahertz holdings and the
proposed 100 megahertz channels, the resulting realignment process for
incumbents would be less complex than using 200 megahertz channels,
because it would result in far fewer partially-filled channels. This
change therefore would further our goals of maximizing efficient use of
this band and allowing this spectrum to be put to use as soon as
possible.
2. Further, changing the band plan from 200 megahertz channels to
100 megahertz channels should not limit this spectrum's potential use
for 5G services. The 100 megahertz channels are consistent with 3GPP
standards, and licensees can aggregate to larger channel sizes (such as
200 megahertz, 300 megahertz, etc.), should they prefer to do so. Given
that 100 megahertz is the baseline to provide 5G services, the
Commission has adopted 100 megahertz channels for other UMFUS bands,
including the 24 GHz band and Lower 37 GHz (37.0-37.6) band, and we
have proposed to adopt 100 megahertz channels for the 42 GHz band.
Adopting 100 megahertz channels in the 39 GHz band is consistent with
our approach in other mmW spectrum bands to support 5G services.
3. We similarly propose to modify the band plan in the Upper 37 GHz
band (37.6-38.6 GHz) from 200 megahertz to 100 megahertz channels. The
Upper 37 GHz band is adjacent to the 39 GHz band, and both bands are
under the same licensing framework. In aligning the regulatory regimes
of these bands--including implementing the same service rules and an
operability requirement--the Commission has effectively treated the two
bands as one contiguous 2,400 megahertz band of spectrum. We further
note that a difference in channel size between the two bands could
create strategic challenges and impede bidding flexibility should the
Commission auction the two bands together.\1\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1\ With respect to auctioning the Upper 37 GHz band, we note
that the Spectrum Frontiers 3rd FNPRM is seeking comment on how best
to accommodate coordination zones in the 37 GHz band for future
Federal operations at a limited number of additional sites, and
whether the coordination zones previously established in Section
30.205 might be reduced to better accommodate nearby non-Federal
operations without adversely impacting Federal operations at those
sites. See Spectrum Frontiers 3rd FNPRM at 30, para. 74; Spectrum
Frontiers R&O, 31 FCC Rcd at 8070-71, para. 149.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
[[Page 42091]]
4. We also propose to modify the band plan for the portion of the
47 GHz band licensed under the UMFUS rules, 47.2-48.2 GHz (47 GHz
band), from 200 to 100 megahertz channels. Modifying the band plan for
the 47 GHz band to 100 megahertz blocks would provide consistency
across the remaining UMFUS bands not yet designated for auction, and
licensees can aggregate spectrum licenses, should they desire larger
bandwidth. If we auction the 47 GHz band at the same time as we auction
the 39 GHz and Upper 37 GHz bands, should all band plans be consistent
100 megahertz blocks?
5. We seek comment on these proposals. Commenters proposing
alternative band plans, including retaining the current 200 megahertz
channels, should specify the benefits of such a plan, particularly with
respect to how it would further our goal of making contiguous spectrum
blocks available for both incumbents and new entrants.
II. Reducing Encumbrances in the 39 GHz Band
A. An Incentive Auction
6. We propose to reconfigure and auction together licenses for all
the available spectrum in the Upper 37 GHz and 39 GHz bands using an
incentive auction. We propose to run a clock auction, in which
incumbents and others may participate, to set both the price of new
licenses and the amounts for which incumbents will relinquish their
spectrum usage rights. This clock auction would simultaneously serve as
the reverse and forward components of the incentive auction. At the end
of the auction, participating incumbent licensees would receive an
incentive payment based on their cancelled incumbent licenses. The
amount of the incentive payment could be used as a credit toward the
licensees' winning bids for any new licenses in any of the bands
offered in the auction. Because the Commission has not previously
conducted an incentive auction in this way, we walk through each step
in turn.
7. As an initial matter, we propose to use a two-phase auction
procedure. In the first phase, participants would bid to win generic
spectrum blocks using an ascending clock auction that would determine a
uniform price in each PEA--this encompasses the simultaneous forward-
and-reverse auction. The second phase would assign specific-frequency
licenses by PEA that would aim to ensure contiguity within each PEA.
Because unencumbered spectrum blocks in the Upper 37 GHz and 39 GHz
bands can be treated as largely interchangeable within a PEA, we
propose to offer these blocks as one category of generic blocks in a
clock auction. We expect that using a clock auction format with bidding
for generic blocks followed by an assignment phase will speed up the
auction considerably relative to a typical FCC simultaneous multiple-
round auction.
8. Specifically, we propose to use a clock auction design with
rules similar to those used for the forward auction in the broadcast
incentive auction and the planned 24 GHz auction. Our proposed clock
auction format would proceed in a series of rounds, with bidding being
conducted simultaneously for all generic spectrum blocks available in
the auction. During the clock phase, the auction would announce prices
for generic blocks in each PEA, and qualified bidders would submit
quantity bids for the number of blocks they seek in the PEA at that
clock price. Bidding rounds would be open for predetermined periods of
time, during which bidders would indicate their demands for blocks at
the clock prices associated with the current round. Bidders would be
subject to activity and eligibility rules that govern the pace at which
they participate in the auction. In each PEA, the clock price for
licenses would increase from round to round if bidders indicate total
demand that exceeds the number of blocks available in the category.
Bidders would be held to their bids, as in the forward phase of the
broadcast incentive auction, with the system only allowing a bidder to
reduce demand if aggregate demand would not fall below the available
supply of blocks in that PEA. The clock rounds would continue until,
for all generic blocks in all geographic areas, the number of blocks
demanded does not exceed the supply of available blocks. At that point,
those bidders indicating demand for a block in a category at the final
clock phase price would be deemed winning bidders.
9. Next, winning bidders from the clock phase would have an
opportunity to submit sealed bids by PEA for particular frequency
blocks in a separate assignment phase. We propose that this assignment
phase be voluntary: Winning bidders need not bid in the assignment
phase. Regardless of its participation in the assignment phase, the
assignment phase would aim to assign contiguous frequency blocks within
a PEA to a bidder that wins multiple blocks.
10. To encourage participation in the reverse auction, we propose
to offer incumbents an incentive payment--using what we term here a
``voucher''--in exchange for the cancellation of certain incumbent
licenses at the end of the auction. Each voucher would have a dollar
value equal to the final clock phase price (for a single generic block
under the new band plan) in the PEA times the ratio of the incumbent's
MHz-pops to the MHz-pops in a full generic block. We note that, by this
definition, a participating incumbent licensee with a license for 100
megahertz of unencumbered spectrum in a PEA could receive a voucher
precisely equal to the cost of paying a winning bid for a license for
the same spectrum in the forward auction. Accordingly, participation in
the clock auction by incumbent licensees will simultaneously be
participation in the forward and reverse auction: The bids for new
blocks in the forward auction automatically set the price of vouchers
that participating incumbent licensees may receive as vouchers in the
reverse auction. As the auction proceeds, the incumbent licensee can
elect whether to pursue new licenses by placing new bids in the forward
auction or to accept the voucher by requesting a reduction in its
demand. Thus, the auction to determine the amount of the winning bid
for the new blocks also serves as the reverse auction that determines
the incentive payment a licensee would receive for voluntarily
relinquishing spectrum usage rights.
11. Although incumbent licensees bidding in the auction would be
free to request a reduction in their demand at any time during the
auction based on their expectations regarding the value of their
vouchers, the Commission itself would not process vouchers until after
the clock auction is over. Provided that the total auction proceeds
exceed the total incentive payments to be shared with licensees
relinquishing spectrum usage rights, we can close the incentive auction
regardless of the proceeds or relinquishments in a particular PEA.
Then, the Commission would process vouchers for each incumbent licensee
in each PEA in two steps, depending on whether all the spectrum made
available in the reverse auction was needed for the forward auction.
First, the Commission would determine whether demand at the end of the
forward auction equaled supply in any given PEA; in those PEAs, the
Commission would cancel the participating
[[Page 42092]]
incumbents' licenses and make payments based on the vouchers.\2\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\2\ For example, if an incumbent licensee had 150 megahertz of
pre-auction spectrum throughout a PEA before the clock auction and
won bids for two 100-megahertz blocks at $10,000 a block in a PEA
where demand equaled supply at the end of the clock auction, that
licensee's pre-auction spectrum licenses would be cancelled, it
would receive a voucher of $15,000 (1.5 x $10,000) and it would owe
$20,000 for the two winning bids (i.e., it would be required to pay
$5,000 net).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
12. In the event that demand by bidders in the forward auction in a
PEA is less than the total supply of blocks offered, we need to address
how to prioritize the blocks supplied by incumbent licensees relative
to the supply of blocks that are held by the FCC in order to determine
whether all incumbent-supplied blocks can be relinquished. That is, if
bidders are interested in obtaining fewer new licenses than the total
number of available blocks, which block or blocks will remain unsold--
those partial or full blocks that an incumbent wishes to relinquish or
those held by the FCC? For example, we could attempt to minimize
payments to incumbent licensees by first satisfying demand with FCC-
held blocks, and then, to the extent possible, with incumbent-offered
blocks. If only some incumbent-held blocks can be used to satisfy
demand, how should we prioritize among incumbent-held blocks? Should we
use a pseudo-random number to break such ties, or should we prioritize
blocks offered by incumbents in a different manner, such as allowing
any incumbents with partial-PEA spectrum usage rights to relinquish
before holders of full-PEA rights, so as to result in a repacked
spectrum blocks that are more consistent with the new band plan?
Alternatively, if we prioritized the reconfiguration of the band by
first satisfying demand with incumbent-held supply, how should we
prioritize which incumbent-held blocks to supply first? We note that,
in situations where the demand for blocks does not exceed the total
supply of blocks, the final clock phase price, at which incentive
payments will be calculated, is likely to be equal to the minimum
opening bid.
13. As a further encouragement for participation in the auction, we
propose to condition bidding for new licenses in the auction on
incumbents' offering their existing spectrum usage rights in the
auction. In other words, an incumbent licensee seeking new licenses in
the forward auction must be a participant in the simultaneous reverse
auction. Such a requirement would ensure that incumbent licensees are
not given a one-way option--purchasing new unencumbered spectrum at
auction while keeping a different set of blocks encumbered and thus
unavailable for an efficient auction.
14. One advantage of this approach is it maximizes the ability of
incumbent licensees to maintain and consolidate their holdings (or to
rationalize their holdings by relinquishing spectrum usage rights in
some areas to acquire rights in other areas) while jointly maximizing
the amount of clear, unencumbered spectrum for auction. Such an
incentive auction appears to be the most efficient path forward to
rationalize the Upper 37 GHz and 39 GHz bands for mobile 5G and high-
speed fixed wireless service. It promotes a rapid transition of the
currently fragmented band while at the same time respecting incumbent
spectrum rights and providing opportunities for entry into the band by
other wireless providers. We seek comment on these proposals and on
alternative approaches to conducting, in a timely manner, an auction of
licenses in the Upper 37 GHz and 39 GHz bands. We also seek comment on
additional incentives we could provide for incumbent licensees to
participate in the reverse auction.
15. A potential concern with the proposed auction is that
incumbents with vouchers may have an incentive to engage in insincere
bidding in markets where they want to be net suppliers of spectrum to
inflate the value of their voucher payments. We seek comment on the
validity of such concerns. We also note that these concerns should be
mitigated by our no withdrawal rule, which we used in the forward phase
of the broadcast incentive auction. We seek comment on any other
potential safeguards that could be implemented against insincere
bidding incentives or other strategic behavior in the proposed
incentive auction.
16. Another potential concern is the interaction of vouchers and
bidding credits. For example, given existing rural and small business
bidding credits, bidders for new licenses may be eligible to receive up
to a 25 percent credit toward their winning bid if they qualify. If
that bidding credit were applied across their gross winning bids, an
incumbent licensee could feasibly retain its existing holdings in the
auction while simultaneously receiving an incentive payment.\3\ To
avoid that result, we propose to limit the application of bidding
credits to cash payments for winning bids in the auction, after the
winning bidder has used any vouchers it has to satisfy winning bids. We
seek comment on this proposal and any other scenarios where the use of
an incentive auction with vouchers may create arbitrage opportunities
given our normal bidding rules. For example, should we address winning
bidders that default on their payments differently here?
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\3\ For example, if a small business incumbent with one 100
megahertz PEA license before the auction won a single license in
that same PEA for $10,000, its voucher would be $10,000 while its
required payment on the one purchased license would be $7,500
($10,000 times 75 percent).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
17. Given that non-incumbent licensees also may qualify for bidding
credits, how should we address the theoretical possibility that auction
proceeds could total less than the incentive payments owed to
incumbents? Should we adopt a rule that would preclude the auction from
closing in the event proceeds from winning bids will be insufficient,
analogous to the final stage rule we adopted in the broadcast
television spectrum incentive auction? Alternatively, should we adopt a
rule to recalculate the amount of incentive payments, so that the
payments do not exceed the available auction proceeds? We seek comment
on these potential possibilities and how to address them. Are there
other particular scenarios in which the auction proceeds might fall
short of the amount needed to pay the face value of vouchers? Or other
methods of addressing such possibilities?
18. We also seek comment on two alternative proposals. First,
incumbents would receive license(s) for all vouchers that are
equivalent to a whole number of new license(s) without bidding at all
in the clock phase. The specific frequencies for these licenses would
be assigned in the assignment round. Under this alternative, incumbent
licenses that are not encumbered would not be able to relinquish
spectrum, and in those PEAs, the total number of blocks offered in the
clock phase would be reduced by the number of 100 megahertz licenses
held by incumbents. In the assignment phase, all blocks won by winning
bidders and all incumbent licenses would be assigned (or in the case of
incumbent licenses, reassigned) frequencies.
19. A second, more narrowly tailored alternative would be to
exchange automatically for vouchers only encumbered PEA and RSA
licenses. Unencumbered PEA licenses would have the option of converting
their unencumbered generic PEA blocks to vouchers if they so choose.
All encumbered licenses would still be required to be converted to
vouchers, since, were these licensees to hold out, this would leave
spectrum that could not fit into the new band plan and
[[Page 42093]]
thereby reduce the efficiency of the auction.
20. Under all these approaches, unencumbered PEA licensees can
obtain new licenses without additional license payments. Under our
proposed approach, however, licensees would have to bid to obtain a new
license, making more licenses available for bidding and increasing the
number of bidders. Making unencumbered PEA licensees bid may increase
the efficiency of the assignment of licenses by having incumbents face
the market price of holding onto their licenses. At a high enough
price, some may relinquish their spectrum to other bidders who value it
more highly. We seek comment on these proposals, particularly from any
current licensee that would choose not to participate in the incentive
auction using one of these three approaches described above or any
other similar approach.
B. A Pre-Auction Voucher Exchange
21. To address concerns raised with respect to incumbent licensees
whose licenses involve RSAs or encumbered PEAs, and thus do not cover
the entire population of a PEA, we propose a pre-auction voucher
exchange.\4\ Much as vouchers in the incentive auction allow incumbent
licensees to consolidate and rationalize their holdings during the
auction, a voucher exchange could allow incumbents to consolidate and
rationalize their holdings before the auction--although in a somewhat
more limited manner. Specifically, it could aid incumbent licensees in
minimizing the number of PEAs going into the auction in which they
would have only fractional vouchers--and thus no ability to assure
themselves that they could exit the auction with a whole number of new
licenses without making net payments to secure their spectrum holdings.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\4\ For encumbered PEA licenses (i.e., licenses that are co-
channel with an RSA license), the licensee's voucher would cover
only the population where it is authorized to operate prior to the
start of the exchange--that is, the area outside of the overlapping
RSA license.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
22. The design of the voucher exchange should allow incumbents to
exchange their fractional vouchers in one or more PEAs, caused by
holding an RSA or encumbered PEA license, to create full vouchers in
another PEA subject to certain restrictions. The first step in a
voucher exchange is to aggregate the vouchers for all encumbered blocks
within a PEA, which is likely to leave a fractional voucher in each
PEA.
23. Next, the Commission would specify exchange rates (expressed on
a per MHz-pop basis) that would allow incumbent licensees to exchange
these fractional vouchers with the Commission. We seek comment on how
to establish the relative exchange rates needed for a voucher exchange.
Should we calculate those exchange rates based on the relative value of
PEA licenses estimated from previous auctions? If so, which prior FCC
auctions should be used to calculate the exchange rates between PEAs?
24. Incumbents would then be allowed to exchange their vouchers
subject to the condition that net trades for each incumbent over all
PEAs be revenue neutral, i.e., aggregate trades up and down will
balance given the FCC-specified exchange rates.\5\ Vouchers could only
be exchanged up or down to no more than the nearest integer above or no
less than the nearest integer below their current fractional voucher
holdings.\6\ If there exists a PEA in which it is not feasible for all
incumbent licensees to ``trade up'' within the 39 GHz band, we propose
that incumbent licensees would only be permitted to ``trade down.'' All
voucher trades with the Commission would be completed prior to the
clock auction phase of the incentive auction. We propose that, before
initiating the voucher exchange, we would educate all potential
participants so that they can understand the process and consequences
of participating in the exchange. We find that this should promote an
efficient process for both the Commission and participants.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\5\ If all of an incumbent's licenses within PEA #1 in the
aggregate cover 20% of the MHz-pops of an unencumbered 100 megahertz
block in PEA #1, the license(s) are represented by a voucher
denominated as 0.2. If all of an incumbent's licenses within a PEA
#2 in the aggregate cover 40 percent of the MHz-pops of an
unencumbered 100 megahertz block in PEA #2, that incumbent's voucher
in PEA #2 would be 0.4. Note that the incumbent's license(s) in PEA
#2 might cover 80 percent of the population in the PEA with only 50
megahertz of bandwidth, or 40 percent of the population with 100
megahertz, or 20 percent of the population with 200 megahertz. A
voucher representing any of these combinations in PEA #2 would be
denominated 0.4. If the exchange rate between PEA #1 and #2 was such
that a voucher in PEA #2 can be exchanged for a voucher of two times
its amount in PEA #1, then the incumbent could exchange its 0.4
voucher in PEA #2 for a PEA #1 voucher for 0.8 (0.4 times two). The
incumbent would then combine its original 0.2 voucher in PEA #1 with
the 0.8 voucher received in the exchange and have a 1.0 voucher in
PEA #1. The incumbent's voucher in PEA #2 would then be 0.0.
\6\ Using our prior example, the limitation that incumbents
cannot increase vouchers to more than the nearest integer above its
initial holdings means that an incumbent with 0.2 in PEA #1 and 0.9
in PEA #2 cannot exchange its PEA #2 voucher for a PEA #1 voucher of
1.8 (0.9 times the exchange rate of two) because the result would
increase the incumbent's holdings in PEA #1 from 0.2 to 2.0, which
is more than the nearest integer above, or 1.0.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
25. We seek comment on this framework for implementing a pre-
auction voucher exchange to serve the public interest, including how
best to address concerns raised in the record with respect to prior
proposals. To establish the framework, we seek comment on the best
methods for achieving our goals. How could a voucher exchange best
facilitate a low cost rapid rationalization of spectrum holdings by
allowing incumbent licensees to aggregate fractional holdings across
PEAs and to retain all their equivalent spectrum usage rights in PEAs
of their choosing to the extent permitted by their fractional holdings
and the exchange rates? Are there any other limits or restrictions that
should be imposed on exchanges that incumbents can make? Separate from
the voucher exchange and building on the Voluntary Rebanding PN, should
we expand the process by which incumbent licensees can modify their
licenses prior to the auction, for example, by allowing for inter-
market swaps using the same exchange rates as the voucher exchange?
26. One restriction we may impose on any exchange that will result
in modified licenses (rather than cancelled licenses and vouchers for
the auction) is to require that any such exchange result in less
geographically encumbered spectrum. Would that serve the public
interest? How should encumbrances be measured? Furthermore, after
exchanging across a number of markets, it is likely that a licensee
will not be able to have full PEA licenses in all markets. One approach
to this remainder would be to set it to zero in that market. Would this
be appropriate, given the opportunity afforded by the exchanges to
minimize such holdings? What other approaches could be taken regarding
such remainders? For example, should an incumbent be permitted to
maintain one fractional license in one PEA?
27. We also seek comment on how the voucher exchange should
interact with existing licenses and the incentive auction. For example,
should we cancel or modify the affected licenses of exchange
participants before the auction in exchange for vouchers? Should we
leave such licenses untouched until after the auction? Should only
incentive auction participants be allowed to participate in the voucher
exchange? Further, should we consider holding this type of voucher
exchange independent of whether we hold an incentive auction to allow
incumbent licensees to combine their fractional licenses into whole
licenses under the new band plan?
[[Page 42094]]
C. Mandatory Repacking
28. We propose to repack incumbent licensees that choose not to
participate in the incentive auction. Just as the Commission repacked
television broadcasters that chose not to participate in the broadcast
incentive auction, the Commission has the authority to modify the
holdings of existing licensees ``if in the judgment of the Commission
such action will promote the public interest, convenience, and
necessity.'' Repacking the holdings of non-participating incumbent
licensees will ensure that we can minimize encumbrances in the band and
maximize the amount of clean spectrum available for auction, while
preserving existing usage rights for incumbents.
29. We seek comment on all aspects of this proposal. We also seek
comment on what criteria to apply when repacking encumbered licenses.
How can the Commission best make modified frequency assignments to
maximize the contiguous spectrum for auction participants while
preserving to the greatest extent possible each incumbent license's
bandwidth, previous geography, and existing contiguity?
30. For example, must or should we maintain frequency contiguity
for RSA licenses that overlap PEAs? Given the requirement of
operability throughout the band, how significant is such contiguity? We
note that partitioning RSAs that overlap multiple PEAs into their
respective PEAs might make it possible to repack more efficiently and
even enable repacked frequencies to be assigned in the auction's
assignment phase.
31. One approach to repacking non-participating incumbents would
involve a two-step calculation. The first step would entail
reconfiguring those incumbent licenses that do not align with PEA
boundaries (e.g., RSA licenses or partial PEA licenses) into full PEA
licenses with an equivalent amount of spectrum in each PEA, as measured
in MHz-pop. The second step would be to restate the incumbent's
fractional holdings of 100 MHz PEA blocks as mostly integer numbers of
100 MHz PEA blocks, in a way that the repacked spectrum maintains the
same value as evaluated with respect to FCC-specified exchange rates
(i.e., those set for the voucher exchange). In all but one of their
PEAs, the fractional holdings of a repacked incumbent would be replaced
by either the nearest integer above or the nearest integer below the
fractional holdings. The one PEA left with fractional holdings would be
the PEA with the smallest possible value. We note that an incumbent
could avoid the effects of such repacking by entering into the
incentive auction.
32. Other efficiencies might be realized by other means. For
example, converting MHz-pops in a geographic area that is less than a
full PEA (i.e., an RSA license or an encumbered PEA license) into the
same MHz-pops in a portion of a 100 megahertz block across the whole
PEA could facilitate more efficient repacking. We note that, depending
on how many and which current licensees choose not to participate in
the incentive auction, there may be some left-over segments, i.e., when
less than a whole 100 megahertz PEA block remains. We seek comment on
whether we should attempt to consolidate such holdout segments in this
manner, and if so whether to auction overlay licenses on them or
otherwise maximize their value for the American public.
33. We seek comment on the options presented above, including
possible variations, and on the costs and benefits of mandatory
repacking for non-participants. Should there be a de minimis spectrum
holdings threshold to qualify for repacking and how should this level
be set? How and when should the frequency reassignment be done in order
to minimize the spectrum required to repack holdout licenses? How
should the adjacent spectrum blocks to the holdout segment be
auctioned, given that they may be less than 100 megahertz?
D. Incentive Auction Legal Authority
34. Congress expressly authorized the Commission to conduct
incentive auctions beyond the broadcast television spectrum incentive
auction. Using this authority, the Commission can offer incentive
payments to licensees that choose to relinquish existing spectrum usage
rights provided by incumbent licenses instead of retaining such rights
pursuant to new licenses. More specifically, the ``Commission may
encourage a licensee to relinquish voluntarily some or all of its
licensed spectrum usage rights in order to permit the assignment of new
initial licenses subject to flexible-use service rules by sharing with
such licensee a portion . . . of the proceeds (including deposits and
upfront payments from successful bidders) from the use of a competitive
bidding system under this subsection.'' To do so, the Commission must
determine ``the value of the relinquished rights . . . in the reverse
auction'' and that reverse auction must have ``at least two competing
licensees participate.''
35. As explained above, we propose to use the clock phase winning
bids for new licenses to determine the incentive payment that
participating incumbent licensees may receive. A participating
incumbent licensee will have a choice between competing in bidding for
new licenses and offering spectrum usage rights or relinquishing
spectrum usage rights under existing licenses in exchange for an
incentive payment.
36. Under the auction design proposed above, any relinquishment of
spectrum usage rights for an incentive payment would be ``voluntary''
within the meaning of the statute. All incumbent licensees may decline
to participate in the incentive auction and instead receive new
licenses that provide spectrum usage rights equivalent to their
existing licenses. Modifying existing licenses in this way does not,
however, require the use of our incentive auction authority. Rather, we
rely on our clear authority to modify license frequencies pursuant to
the public interest. Given that incumbent licensees will participate in
the incentive auction by choice, we conclude that any subsequent
decision an incumbent doing so makes to relinquish spectrum usage
rights should be considered voluntary. We seek comment on our
conclusion.
37. We propose above that incumbent licensees that choose not to
participate in the reverse auction may not participate in the auction
of new licenses. Could that additional consequence of choosing not to
participate affect whether a subsequent relinquishment is voluntary? An
incumbent licensee that chooses between relinquishing spectrum usage
rights for an incentive payment or instead receiving new licenses for
equivalent spectrum usage rights at no additional cost presumably does
so voluntarily, regardless of whether it chose to participate because
of some collateral consequence of non-participation. Nothing compels
such a licensee to make the relinquishment instead of retaining its
spectrum usage rights under new licenses.
38. We also conclude that our proposal that incumbent licensees
that choose not to participate in the reverse auction may not
participate in the forward auction of new licenses is consistent with
our authority to determine qualifications that auction participants
must satisfy. More specifically, we conclude that the proposed
consequence of an incumbent's choice would constitute a rule of general
applicability regarding auction participation. We seek comment on these
conclusions.
[[Page 42095]]
39. Our proposal satisfies additional statutory requirements for
our incentive auction authority. The ``reverse'' nature of the auction
required by the statute is one in which those rights are relinquished
by licensees to the Commission, reversing the typical flow of rights
assigned based on spectrum license auctions. Although auctions in other
contexts--such as the Connect America Fund Phase II Auction to
distribute universal service support for high-speed broadband
deployment in rural America--are sometimes called reverse auctions
because the price declines over the course of bidding, nothing in the
statute requires that a reverse auction to relinquish spectrum usage
rights use descending bidding. We note that in the broadcast television
spectrum incentive auction, the Commission chose to use a descending
clock price auction for the reverse auction component because a
descending clock auction design involved several features that were
particularly helpful in that context, not because it was statutorily
required.
40. We also conclude that, so long as at least two incumbent
licensees with licenses in the same PEA choose to participate in the
incentive auction, the reverse auction will meet the statutory
requirement to have at least ``two competing licensees
participat[ing]'' in the reverse auction.\7\ In the broadcast
television spectrum incentive auction, the Commission concluded that at
least two licensees participate in the reverse auction so long as more
than one non-commonly controlled party qualifies as an applicant to
participate in the auction. This is so because any qualified applicant
that bids in the auction must take into account the presence of another
qualified applicant that has the opportunity to bid, regardless of
whether the second applicant in fact bids. We find that same conclusion
should apply here, too. Incumbents seeking to relinquish spectrum usage
rights in the proposed auction must take into account the demand for
new licenses by other qualified applicants, as they only will be able
to relinquish rights so long as demand for new licenses exceeds supply.
We seek comment on this analysis.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\7\ See Incentive Auction Report and Order, 29 FCC Rcd at 6742,
para. 413. The Commission took care to note that it might ``apply
[the two competing participants] requirement differently in other
reverse auctions, depending upon the particular eligibility
criteria, auction design and other circumstances.'' Id. at 6743,
para. 414 n.1224. Accordingly, while we find the discussion
regarding this requirement helpful, it is not controlling.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
41. Further, we seek comment generally on whether our proposal to
conduct an auction with the elements described above or any of our
alternative scenarios for conducting an incentive auction would be
consistent with our statutory authority to conduct an incentive
auction. To the extent that commenters assert that these scenarios are
not consistent with our incentive auction authority, commenters should
discuss any changes that could more fully satisfy that authority.
42. As noted above in our proposal, we have authority to modify the
holdings of existing licensees based on our judgment of the public
interest. We conclude that the potential modifications considered above
are within our authority. We ask that commenters proposing further
modifications to address whether their proposals are within our
authority.
43. Legal Authority for Alternative Auction Mechanisms. We seek
comment on alternative legal authority should we decide not to conduct
an incentive auction. For example, we seek comment on whether we might
conduct an auction as described above while providing current licensees
with bidding offset credits in place of vouchers and incentive
payments. We seek comment on whether issuing bidding offset credits in
order to protect existing spectrum uses--and past Commission public
interest judgments reflected in prior licensing decisions--while
clearing existing spectrum assignments is necessary to the management
of spectrum in the public interest and not inconsistent with the
Communications Act. Effectively clearing prior spectrum assignments so
that new licenses for this spectrum may be assigned by competitive
bidding will promote statutory objectives. Issuing bidding offset
credits is within the Commission's statutory authority regarding the
design of competitive bidding systems. Section 309(j)(4) of the
Communications Act grants the Commission authority to consider a
variety of methods of helping entities pay for licenses that are
offered at auction, including alternative payment schedules, tax
credits, and bidding preferences.
44. We ask commenters to address the differences, if any, in
incentives provided to current licensees by providing them with a
bidding offset credit without an opportunity to receive an incentive
payment. Commenters should address the likely differences in the
outcome of the auction resulting from such different incentives, and
whether providing incentive payments would better serve the public
interest, notwithstanding the need to share a portion of the auction
proceeds. Would the amount of repurposed spectrum be affected? We also
seek comment on any other approaches that might achieve the purposes of
the proposal without sharing proceeds from the auction of new licenses
with existing licensees.
III. Initial Regulatory Flexibility Analysis
45. As required by the Regulatory Flexibility Act of 1980, as
amended (RFA), the Commission has prepared this present Initial
Regulatory Flexibility Analysis (IRFA) of the possible significant
economic impact on a substantial number of small entities by the
policies and rules proposed in the attached 4th FNPRM . Written public
comments are requested on this IRFA. Comments must be identified as
responses to the IRFA and must be filed by the deadlines for comments
as specified in the 4th FNPRM. The Commission will send a copy of this
4th FNPRM, including this IRFA, to the Chief Counsel for Advocacy of
the Small Business Administration (SBA). In addition, the 4th FNPRM and
IRFA (or summaries thereof) will be published in the Federal Register.
A. Need for, and Objectives of, the Proposed Rules
46. In the 4th FNPRM, we propose to modify the band plan for the
38.6-40 GHz (39 GHz) band to 100 megahertz channels for the Part 30
Upper Microwave Flexible Use Service (UMFUS), and propose to similarly
modify the 37.6-38.6 GHz (Upper 37 GHz) and 47.2-48.2 GHz (47 GHz)
bands to 100 megahertz channels if we adopt the 100 megahertz channel
plan for the 39 GHz band. The 4th FNPRM also seeks comment on which
auction mechanism to use to realign existing 39 GHz licenses.
47. First, we propose to modify the 39 GHz band plan from seven 200
megahertz to fourteen 100 megahertz channels to allow for better
consolidation of existing license holdings. We propose modifying the
Upper 37 GHz band plan from 200 megahertz to 100 megahertz channels,
given that the two bands are adjacent and have the same service rules
and an operability requirement. Further, in the 4th FNPRM we propose to
auction the 39 GHz and Upper 37 bands together. In addition we propose
to modify the 47 GHz band plan from 200 to 100 megahertz channels if we
auction all three bands at the same time and seek comment on that
proposal.
48. Second, we propose to use a two-phase incentive auction. In the
first phase, participants would bid to win generic spectrum blocks
using an
[[Page 42096]]
ascending clock auction that would determine a uniform price in each
PEA--this encompasses the simultaneous forward-and-reverse auction. The
second phase would assign specific-frequency licenses by PEA that would
aim to ensure contiguity within each PEA. Because the spectrum blocks
in the Upper 37 GHz and 39 GHz bands can be treated as largely
interchangeable within a PEA, we propose to offer unencumbered blocks
as one category of generic blocks in a clock auction. Specifically, we
propose to use a clock auction design with rules similar to those used
for the forward auction in the broadcast incentive auction and the
planned 24 GHz auction. Next, winning bidders from the clock phase
would have an opportunity to submit sealed bids by PEA for particular
frequency blocks in a separate assignment phase. We propose that this
assignment phase be voluntary: Winning bidders need not bid in the
assignment phase. Regardless of its participation in the assignment
phase, the assignment phase would aim to assign contiguous frequency
blocks within a PEA to a bidder that wins multiple blocks.
49. We propose to encourage incumbent licensees to participate in
the reverse auction by offering them an incentive payment--using what
we term here a ``voucher''--in exchange for the cancellation of certain
incumbent licenses at the end of the auction. Each voucher would have a
dollar value equal to the final clock phase price (for a single generic
block under the new band plan) in the PEA in which the incumbent
license is located times the ratio of bandwidth provided by the
incumbent's license and the population that can be reached using that
license within a given PEA (expressed in MHz-pops) divided by the
bandwidth and population reached by a generic block (expressed in MHz-
pops). We propose to further encourage incumbent licensees to
participate in the reverse auction by requiring such participation if
the incumbent licensee seeks to participate in the accompanying forward
auction. In addition, we seek comment on two alternative auction
proposals. First, incumbents would receive license(s) for all vouchers
that are equivalent to a whole number of new license(s) without bidding
at all in the clock phase. In the assignment phase, all blocks won by
winning bidders and all incumbent licenses would be assigned (or in the
case of incumbent licenses, reassigned) frequencies. We seek comment on
a second alternative in which we would exchange automatically for
vouchers only encumbered PEA and RSA licenses.
50. Third, we propose a pre-auction voucher exchange process in
which incumbents can trade fractional license holdings for full license
holdings--including across markets in some circumstances--under the new
band plan, with these trades reflected as full vouchers in the auction.
The exchange would allow incumbents to aggregate fractional holdings
across PEAs and to retain all their equivalent spectrum usage rights in
PEAs of their choosing to the extent permitted by their fractional
holdings and the exchange rates. We seek comment on establishing the
relative exchange rates needed for a voucher exchange. We seek comment
on a framework for implementing a pre-auction voucher exchange to serve
the public interest, including how best to address concerns raised in
the record with respect to prior proposals.
51. Fourth, we propose to repack incumbent licensees that choose
not to participate in reverse auction portion of the incentive auction.
Repacking the holdings of non-participating incumbent licensees will
ensure that we can minimize encumbrances in the band, maximizing the
amount of clean spectrum available for auction, while preserving
existing usage rights for incumbents. We propose that licensees that
choose to repack encumbered licenses in lieu of exchanging for vouchers
should not be allowed to bid on new licenses in either the clock phase
of the auction or be allowed to bid on frequency assignments during the
assignment round. Prohibiting auction participation for such licensees
would create a strong incentive for incumbents to choose to exchange
all of their licenses for vouchers.
52. Lastly, we propose to auction together all licenses in the
Upper 37 GHz and 39 GHz, using the Commission's incentive auction
authority, where existing 39 GHz license holders could relinquish their
spectrum usage rights in return for an incentive payment, and/or
acquire new rights. We conclude that the auction design we propose
would satisfy the requirement to conduct a reverse auction to determine
the amount of compensation licensees would accept for voluntarily
relinquishing spectrum usage rights. All incumbent licensees may
decline to participate in the incentive auction and instead receive new
licenses that provide spectrum usage rights equivalent to their
existing licenses. We seek comment on our proposal to condition bidding
for new licenses in the auction on incumbents' offering their existing
spectrum usage rights in the auction. Such a requirement would ensure
that incumbent licensees are not given a one-way option--purchasing new
unencumbered spectrum at auction while keeping a different set of
blocks encumbered and thus unavailable for an efficient auction.
Furthermore, in case we were to conclude that the auction design
proposed above would not satisfy the statutory requirements for an
incentive auction, we seek comment on alternatives in which auction
proceeds are not shared with incumbents, such as providing current
licensees with bidding offset credits in place of vouchers
53. Overall, the proposals in the 4th FNPRM are designed to
facilitate broadband deployment, including 5G services, by providing
opportunities to make it easier for licensees in the band to
rationalize their existing holdings into contiguous swathes of
spectrum, and by offering new licenses of contiguous spectrum at
auction while protecting incumbents' existing spectrum usage rights.
This will ensure that this spectrum is efficiently used and will foster
the development of new and innovative technologies and services, as
well as encourage the growth and development of a wide variety of
services, ultimately leading to greater benefits to consumers.
B. Legal Basis
54. The proposed action is authorized pursuant to Sections 1, 2, 3,
4, 5, 7, 301, 302, 302a, 303, 304, 307, 309, and 310 of the
Communications Act of 1934, as amended, 47 U.S.C. 151, 152, 153, 154,
155, 157, 301, 302, 302a, 303, 304, 307, 309, and 310, Section 706 of
the Telecommunications Act of 1996, as amended, 47 U.S.C. 1302.
C. Description and Estimate of the Number of Small Entities to Which
the Proposed Rules Will Apply
55. The RFA directs agencies to provide a description of and, where
feasible, an estimate of the number of small entities that may be
affected by the proposed rules, if adopted. The RFA generally defines
the term ``small entity'' as having the same meaning as the terms
``small business,'' ``small organization,'' and ``small governmental
jurisdiction.'' In addition, the term ``small business'' has the same
meaning as the term ``small business concern'' under the Small Business
Act.'' A ``small business concern'' is one which: (1) Is independently
owned and operated; (2) is not dominant in its field of operation; and
(3) satisfies any additional criteria established by the SBA.
[[Page 42097]]
56. Small Businesses, Small Organizations, Small Governmental
Jurisdictions. Our actions, over time, may affect small entities that
are not easily categorized at present. We therefore describe here, at
the outset, three broad groups of small entities that could be directly
affected herein. First, while there are industry specific size
standards for small businesses that are used in the regulatory
flexibility analysis, according to data from the SBA's Office of
Advocacy, in general a small business is an independent business having
fewer than 500 employees. These types of small businesses represent
99.9% of all businesses in the United States which translates to 28.8
million businesses.
57. Next, the type of small entity described as a ``small
organization'' is generally ``any not-for-profit enterprise which is
independently owned and operated and is not dominant in its field.''
Nationwide, as of August 2016, there were approximately 356,494 small
organizations based on registration and tax data filed by nonprofits
with the Internal Revenue Service (IRS).
58. Finally, the small entity described as a ``small governmental
jurisdiction'' is defined generally as ``governments of cities,
counties, towns, townships, villages, school districts, or special
districts, with a population of less than fifty thousand.'' U.S. Census
Bureau data from the 2012 Census of Governments indicate that there
were 90,056 local governmental jurisdictions consisting of general
purpose governments and special purpose governments in the United
States. Of this number there were 37,132 General purpose governments
(county, municipal and town or township) with populations of less than
50,000 and 12,184 Special purpose governments (independent school
districts and special districts) with populations of less than 50,000.
The 2012 U.S. Census Bureau data for most types of governments in the
local government category show that the majority of these governments
have populations of less than 50,000. Based on this data we estimate
that at least 49,316 local government jurisdictions fall in the
category of ``small governmental jurisdictions.''
59. Wireless Telecommunications Carriers (except Satellite). This
industry comprises establishments engaged in operating and maintaining
switching and transmission facilities to provide communications via the
airwaves. Establishments in this industry have spectrum licenses and
provide services using that spectrum, such as cellular services, paging
services, wireless internet access, and wireless video services. The
appropriate size standard under SBA rules is that such a business is
small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees. For this industry, U.S.
Census Bureau data for 2012 show that there were 967 firms that
operated for the entire year. Of this total, 955 firms had employment
of 999 or fewer employees and 12 had employment of 1,000 employees or
more. Thus under this category and the associated size standard, the
Commission estimates that the majority of wireless telecommunications
carriers (except satellite) are small entities.
60. Fixed Microwave Services. Microwave services include common
carrier, private-operational fixed, and broadcast auxiliary radio
services. They also include the Upper Microwave Flexible Use Service,
the Millimeter Wave Service, Local Multipoint Distribution Service
(LMDS), the Digital Electronic Message Service (DEMS), and the 24 GHz
Service, where licensees can choose between common carrier and non-
common carrier status. At present, there are approximately 66,680
common carrier fixed licensees, 69,360 private and public safety
operational-fixed licensees, 20,150 broadcast auxiliary radio
licensees, 411 LMDS licenses, 33 24 GHz DEMS licenses, 777 39 GHz
licenses, and five 24 GHz licensees, and 467 Millimeter Wave licenses
in the microwave services. The Commission has not yet defined a small
business with respect to microwave services. The closest applicable SBA
category is Wireless Telecommunications Carriers (except Satellite) and
the appropriate size standard for this category under SBA rules is that
such a business is small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees. For this
industry, U.S. Census Bureau data for 2012 shows that there were 967
firms that operated for the entire year. Of this total, 955 had
employment of 999 or fewer, and 12 firms had employment of 1,000
employees or more. Thus under this SBA category and the associated
standard, the Commission estimates that the majority of fixed microwave
service licensees can be considered small.
61. The Commission does not have data specifying the number of
these licensees that have more than 1,500 employees, and thus is unable
at this time to estimate with greater precision the number of fixed
microwave service licensees that would qualify as small business
concerns under the SBA's small business size standard. Consequently,
the Commission estimates that there are up to 36,708 common carrier
fixed licensees and up to 59,291 private operational-fixed licensees
and broadcast auxiliary radio licensees in the microwave services that
may be small and may be affected by the rules and policies proposed
herein. We note, however, that both the common carrier microwave fixed
and the private operational microwave fixed licensee categories
includes some large entities.
62. All Other Telecommunications. The ``All Other
Telecommunications'' category is comprised of establishments primarily
engaged in providing specialized telecommunications services, such as
satellite tracking, communications telemetry, and radar station
operation. This industry also includes establishments primarily engaged
in providing satellite terminal stations and associated facilities
connected with one or more terrestrial systems and capable of
transmitting telecommunications to, and receiving telecommunications
from, satellite systems. Establishments providing internet services or
voice over internet protocol (VoIP) services via client-supplied
telecommunications connections are also included in this industry.''
The SBA has developed a small business size standard for ``All Other
Telecommunications,'' which consists of all such firms with gross
annual receipts of $32.5 million or less. For this category, U.S.
Census Bureau data for 2012 shows that there were a total of 1,442
firms that operated for the entire year. Of these firms, a total of
1400 firms had gross annual receipts of under $25 million and 42 firms
had gross annual receipts of $25 million to $49,999,999. Thus, the
Commission estimates that a majority of ``All Other
Telecommunications'' firms potentially affected by our actions can be
considered small.
63. Radio and Television Broadcasting and Wireless Communications
Equipment Manufacturing. This industry comprises establishments
primarily engaged in manufacturing radio and television broadcast and
wireless communications equipment. Examples of products made by these
establishments are: Transmitting and receiving antennas, cable
television equipment, GPS equipment, pagers, cellular phones, mobile
communications equipment, and radio and television studio and
broadcasting equipment.'' The SBA has established a size standard for
this industry of 1,250 employees or less. U.S. Census Bureau data for
2012 shows that 841 establishments operated in this industry in that
year. Of that number, 828 establishments operated with fewer than 1,000
employees, 7 establishments operated with between 1,000 and 2,499
employees and 6 establishments
[[Page 42098]]
operated with 2,500 or more employees. Based on this data, we conclude
that a majority of manufacturers in this industry is small.
D. Description of Projected Reporting, Recordkeeping, and Other
Compliance Requirements
64. We expect the rules and procedures proposed in the 4th FNPRM
will impose new or additional reporting or recordkeeping and/or other
compliance obligations on small entities as well as other licensees
with licenses in the 39 GHz band issued prior to the auction of new
licenses proposed in the 4th FNPRM. The proposed rules and procedures
would require parties with licenses in the 39 GHz band issued prior to
the auction of new licenses proposed in the 4th FNPRM to provide
certain information following the auction of the new licenses.
Depending upon the licensee's individual circumstances, the information
required may include directions regarding the cancellation of pre-
existing licenses, directions regarding a choice between satisfying
winning bids for new licenses and receiving incentive payments, and
directions regarding how any incentive payments are to be made.
65. The projected reporting, recordkeeping, and other compliance
requirements resulting from this proceeding would apply to all such
licensees in the same manner. The Commission believes that applying the
same rules equally to all entities in this context would promote
fairness. We note that eight of the existing fourteen such licensees
may be considered small entities. The Commission does not believe that
the costs and/or administrative burdens associated with the rules would
unduly burden small entities. Moreover, the proposed reverse auction
would benefit any affected small entities by providing an opportunity
to receive an incentive payment in exchange for spectrum usage rights.
E. Steps Taken To Minimize Significant Economic Impact on Small
Entities, and Significant Alternatives Considered
66. The RFA requires an agency to describe any significant
alternatives for small businesses that it has considered in reaching
its proposed approach, which may include the following four
alternatives (among others): (1) The establishment of differing
compliance or reporting requirements or timetables that take into
account the resources available to small entities; (2) the
clarification, consolidation, or simplification of compliance and
reporting requirements under the rule for such small entities; (3) the
use of performance rather than design standards; and (4) an exemption
from coverage of the rule, or any part thereof, for such small
entities.
67. The Commission does not believe that its proposed changes will
have a significant economic impact on small entities. We believe that
modifying the band plan from 200 megahertz to 100 megahertz channels in
the 39 GHz, Upper 37 GHz, and 47 GHz bands will help small entities by
making spectrum available in smaller license sizes that may be more
attractive to small entities. We also believe the proposed mechanism
for auctioning the 39 GHz and Upper 37 GHz bands would facilitate
access to spectrum by small businesses and a wide variety of other
entities, while preserving incumbent licensees' spectrum rights.
However, to get a better understanding of costs and any burdens, we
seek comment on whether any of the burdens associated with the proposed
rules and policies can be minimized for small businesses. The
Commission expects to more fully consider the economic impact and
alternatives for small entities following the review of comments filed
in response to the 4th FNPRM.
F. Federal Rules That May Duplicate, Overlap, or Conflict With the
Proposed Rules
68. None.
IV. Ordering Clauses
69. It is ordered, pursuant to the authority found in Sections 1,
2, 3, 4, 5, 7, 301, 302, 303, 304, 307, 309, 310, and 316 of the
Communications Act of 1934, 47 U.S.C. 151, 152, 153, 154, 155, 157,
301, 302, 303, 304, 307, 309, 310, and 316, and Sec. 1.411 of the
Commission's Rules, 47 CFR 1.411, that this 4th FNPRM is hereby
adopted.
70. It is further ordered that the Commission's Consumer and
Governmental Affairs Bureau, Reference Information Center, shall send a
copy of this 4th FNPRM, including the Initial Regulatory Flexibility
Analysis, to the Chief Counsel for Advocacy of the Small Business
Administration.
List of Subjects in 47 CFR Part 30
Communications common carriers, Reporting and recordkeeping
requirements, Communications equipment.
Federal Communications Commission.
Katura Jackson,
Federal Register Liaison Officer, Office of the Secretary.
Proposed Rules
For the reasons discussed in the preamble, the Federal
Communications Commission proposes to amend 47 CFR part 30 as follows:
PART 30--UPPER MICROWAVE FLEXIBLE USE SERVICE
0
1. The authority citation for part 30 continues to read as follows:
Authority: 47 U.S.C. 151, 152, 153, 154, 301, 303, 304, 307,
309, 310, 316, 332, 1302.
0
2. Amend Sec. 30.4 by:
0
a. Redesignating paragraphs (b) through (e) as paragraphs (c), (d),
(f), and (g);
0
b. Adding and reserving new paragraphs (b) and (e); and
0
c. Revising redesignated paragraphs (d)(1), (f), and (g).
The revisions and addition read as follows:
Sec. 30.4 Frequencies.
* * * * *
(b) [Reserved]
* * * * *
(d) * * *
(1) New channel plan:
------------------------------------------------------------------------
Frequency band
Channel No. limits (MHz)
------------------------------------------------------------------------
1.................................................... 38,600-38,700
2.................................................... 38,700-38,800
3.................................................... 38,800-38,900
4.................................................... 38,900-39,000
5.................................................... 39,000-39,100
6.................................................... 39,100-39,200
7.................................................... 39,200-39,300
8.................................................... 39,300-39,400
9.................................................... 39,400-39,500
10................................................... 39,500-39,600
11................................................... 39,600-39,700
12................................................... 39,700-39,800
13................................................... 39,800-39,900
14................................................... 39,900-40,000
------------------------------------------------------------------------
* * * * *
[[Page 42099]]
(e) [Reserved]
(f) 37-38.6 GHz band: 37,600-37,700; 37,700-37,800 MHz; 37,800-
37,900 MHz; 37,900-38,000 MHz; 38,000-38,100 MHz; 38,100-38,200 MHz;
38,200-38,300 MHz; 38,300-38,400 MHz; 38,400-38,500 MHz, and 38,500-
38,600 MHz. The 37,000-37,600 MHz band segment shall be available on a
site-specific, coordinated shared basis with eligible Federal entities.
(g) 47.2-48.2 GHz band--47.2-47.3 GHz; 47.3-47.4 GHz; 47.4-47.5
GHz; 47.5-47.6 GHz; 47.6-47.7 GHz; 47.7-47.8 GHz; 47.8-47.9 GHz; 47.9-
48.0 GHz; 48.0-48.1 GHz; and 48.1-48.2 GHz.
[FR Doc. 2018-17820 Filed 8-17-18; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6712-01-P