Updating the Intercarrier Compensation Regime To Eliminate Access Arbitrage, 30628-30639 [2018-13699]
Download as PDF
30628
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 126 / Friday, June 29, 2018 / Proposed Rules
C. Removal of Expired Rule
Idaho submitted Docket 58–0101–
1602 that repealed IDAPA 58.01.01.582
‘‘Interim Conformity Provisions for
Northern Ada County Former
Nonattainment Area for PM–10’’
(section 582) because it was outdated
and no longer applicable. Section 582
was promulgated in 2001 as a temporary
measure that was necessary only until a
required maintenance plan could be
developed to address CAA
transportation conformity requirements
for the PM10 Ada County nonattainment
area. Idaho has since developed and
adopted the required maintenance plan
and EPA approved the maintenance
plan on October 27, 2003 (68 FR 61106),
effective November 26, 2003. Idaho
repealed the expired section 582 (state
effective March 28, 2017) and submitted
the revision to EPA. EPA is therefore
proposing to remove section 582 from
Idaho’s SIP as requested by Idaho in its
April 12, 2018 SIP submittal.
III. Proposed Action
EPA is proposing to approve, and
incorporate by reference where
appropriate, in Idaho’s SIP all revisions
to IDAPA 58.01.01.107 Incorporations
by Reference, except .03.f through .p
(state effective March 28, 2018) as
requested by Idaho on March 20, 2018,
and as described in Section II.B. above.
EPA is also proposing, as requested by
Idaho on April 12, 2018, to remove
IDAPA 58.01.01.582 Interim Conformity
Provisions for Northern Ada County
Former Nonattainment Area for PM 10
from the Idaho SIP because it expired in
2003 and Idaho has repealed it as a
matter of state law (state effective March
29, 2017). See Section II.C. (above).
We have made the preliminary
determination that the submitted SIP
revisions are consistent with section 110
and part C of Title I of the CAA.
sradovich on DSK3GMQ082PROD with PROPOSALS
IV. Incorporation by Reference
In this rule, EPA is proposing to
include in a final rule, regulatory text
that includes incorporation by
reference. In accordance with
requirements of 1 CFR 51.5, EPA is
proposing to incorporate by reference
the provisions described above in
Section III. Also in this rule, EPA is
proposing to remove, in a final EPA
rule, regulatory text that includes
incorporation by reference. In
accordance with requirements of 1 CFR
51.5, EPA is proposing to remove the
incorporation by reference of IDAPA
58.01.01.582 as described in Section III.
EPA has made, and will continue to
make, these documents generally
available electronically through
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:09 Jun 28, 2018
Jkt 244001
www.regulations.gov and in hard copy
at the appropriate EPA office (see the
ADDRESSES section of this preamble for
more information).
V. Statutory and Executive Orders
Review
Under the Clean Air Act, the
Administrator is required to approve a
SIP submission that complies with the
provisions of the Act and applicable
Federal regulations. 42 U.S.C. 7410(k);
40 CFR 52.02(a). Thus, in reviewing SIP
submissions, the EPA’s role is to
approve state choices, provided that
they meet the criteria of the Clean Air
Act. Accordingly, this proposed action
merely approves state law as meeting
Federal requirements and does not
impose additional requirements beyond
those imposed by state law. For that
reason, this proposed action:
• Is not a ‘‘significant regulatory
action’’ subject to review by the Office
of Management and Budget under
Executive Orders 12866 (58 FR 51735,
October 4, 1993) and 13563 (76 FR 3821,
January 21, 2011);
• Is not an Executive Order 13771 (82
FR 9339, February 2, 2017) regulatory
action because SIP approvals are
exempted under Executive Order 12866;
• Does not impose an information
collection burden under the provisions
of the Paperwork Reduction Act (44
U.S.C. 3501 et seq.);
• Is certified as not having a
significant economic impact on a
substantial number of small entities
under the Regulatory Flexibility Act (5
U.S.C. 601 et seq.);
• Does not contain any unfunded
mandate or significantly or uniquely
affect small governments, as described
in the Unfunded Mandates Reform Act
of 1995 (Pub. L. 104–4);
• Does not have Federalism
implications as specified in Executive
Order 13132 (64 FR 43255, August 10,
1999);
• Is not an economically significant
regulatory action based on health or
safety risks subject to Executive Order
13045 (62 FR 19885, April 23, 1997);
• Is not a significant regulatory action
subject to Executive Order 13211 (66 FR
28355, May 22, 2001);
• Is not subject to requirements of
Section 12(d) of the National
Technology Transfer and Advancement
Act of 1995 (15 U.S.C. 272 note) because
it does not involve technical standards;
and
• Does not provide the EPA with the
discretionary authority to address, as
appropriate, disproportionate human
health or environmental effects, using
practicable and legally permissible
PO 00000
Frm 00040
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
methods, under Executive Order 12898
(59 FR 7629, February 16, 1994).
The proposed SIP would not be
approved to apply on any Indian
reservation land or in any other area
where the EPA or an Indian tribe has
demonstrated that a tribe has
jurisdiction. In those areas of Indian
country, the proposed rule does not
have tribal implications and will not
impose substantial direct costs on tribal
governments or preempt tribal law as
specified by Executive Order 13175 (65
FR 67249, November 9, 2000).
List of Subjects in 40 CFR Part 52
Environmental protection, Air
pollution control, Incorporation by
reference, Intergovernmental relations,
Ozone, Particulate matter, Reporting
and recordkeeping requirements, Sulfur
oxides, Volatile organic compounds.
Authority: 42 U.S.C. 7401 et seq.
Dated: June 20, 2018.
Michelle L. Pirzadeh,
Regional Administrator, Region 10.
[FR Doc. 2018–14096 Filed 6–28–18; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6560–50–P
FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS
COMMISSION
47 CFR Part 51
[WC Docket No. 18–155; FCC 18–68]
Updating the Intercarrier
Compensation Regime To Eliminate
Access Arbitrage
Federal Communications
Commission.
ACTION: Proposed rule.
AGENCY:
In this document, the
Commission proposed to adopt rules to
curb the financial incentive to engage in
access stimulation by giving accessstimulating LECs two choices for
receiving calls. The access-stimulating
LEC can choose either: To be financially
responsible for the delivery of calls to
its network, in which case intermediate
access providers would charge the
access-stimulating LEC for the delivery
of calls; or to accept direct connections
from long distance carriers seeking to
terminate telephone calls to the LEC or
from intermediate access providers of
the long distance carriers’ choosing,
which would allow the long distance
carriers to bypass intermediate access
providers chosen by the accessstimulating LEC. This document seeks
comment on several alternatives,
including requiring LECs engaged in
access stimulation to immediately
transition their terminating access
SUMMARY:
E:\FR\FM\29JNP1.SGM
29JNP1
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 126 / Friday, June 29, 2018 / Proposed Rules
charges to bill-and-keep. This document
also seeks comment on the effect the
proposed rules will have on specific
arbitrage schemes described in the
record. Finally, it seeks comment on
how to curb other arbitrage schemes.
DATES: Comments are due on or before
July 20, 2018; reply comments are due
on or before August 3, 2018.
ADDRESSES: You may submit comments,
identified by WC Docket No. 18–155, by
any of the following methods:
• Federal Communications
Commission’s website: https://
apps.fcc.gov/ecfs//. Follow the
instructions for submitting comments.
• People with Disabilities: Contact the
FCC to request reasonable
accommodations (accessible format
documents, sign language interpreters,
CART, etc.) by email: FCC504@fcc.gov
or phone: 202–418–0530 or TTY: 888–
835–5322.
For detailed instructions for
submitting comments and additional
information on the rulemaking process,
see the SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION
section of this document.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
Edward Krachmer, FCC Wireline
Competition Bureau, Pricing Policy
Division at 202–418–1525, or at
Edward.Krachmer@fcc.gov.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: This is a
summary of the Commission’s Notice of
Proposed Rulemaking (NPRM), WC
Docket No. 18–155; FCC 18–68, adopted
on June 4, 2018 and released on June 5,
2018. The full text of this document
may be obtained at the following
internet address: https://www.fcc.gov/
document/fcc-proposes-reformseliminate-intercarrier-compensationarbitrage.
I. Background
sradovich on DSK3GMQ082PROD with PROPOSALS
A. The Current Access Stimulation
Rules
1. To reduce access stimulation, as
part of the USF/ICC Transformation
Order, 76 FR 73860, FCC 11–161, the
Commission defined ‘‘access
stimulation’’ as occurring when two
conditions are met. First, the involved
LEC must have a ‘‘revenue sharing
agreement,’’ which may be ‘‘express,
implied, written or oral’’ that ‘‘over the
course of the agreement, would directly
or indirectly result in a net payment to
the other party (including affiliates) to
the agreement, in which payment’’ by
the LEC is ‘‘based on the billing or
collection of access charges from
interexchange carriers or wireless
carriers.’’ Second, the LEC must also
meet one of two traffic tests. An accessstimulating LEC either has ‘‘an interstate
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:09 Jun 28, 2018
Jkt 244001
terminating-to-originating traffic ratio of
at least 3:1 in a calendar month, has had
more than a 100 percent growth in
interstate originating and/or terminating
switched access minutes of use in a
month compared to the same month in
the preceding year.’’ Even if a LEC no
longer meets either of these traffic tests,
once it is considered to have engaged in
access stimulation, this regulatory
classification persists so long as the LEC
maintains any revenue sharing
agreement.
2. A LEC that is engaged in access
stimulation is required by our rules to
reduce its access charges either by
adjusting its rates to account for its high
traffic volumes (if a rate-of-return LEC)
or to reduce its access charges to those
of the price cap LEC with the lowest
switched access rates in the state (if a
competitive LEC). These reduced rates
lower the cost to interexchange carriers
(IXCs) and the amount received by the
LEC and the provider of high call
volume services with which it has a
revenue sharing agreement.
B. Arbitrage Schemes After the USF/ICC
Transformation Order
3. Last year, the Wireline Competition
Bureau (Bureau) issued a public
notification, 82 FR 44754, seeking to
refresh the record on ICC issues raised
by the Commission in the USF/ICC
Transformation Order. In response to
that public notification, commenters
argue that, notwithstanding prior
Commission action, arbitrage continues
as ‘‘companies engaged in access
stimulation use a variety of tactics to
prevent interexchange carriers from
avoiding their excessive charges.’’ The
record indicates that today’s access
arbitrage schemes are often enabled by
the use of intermediate access providers
selected by the terminating LECs. When
an intermediate access provider is in the
call path, the IXC pays access charges
on a per-minute-of-use (MOU) basis to
the intermediate access provider and to
the terminating LEC. This tactic evades
existing Commission rules intended to
stop access stimulation to the extent
that an intermediate access provider is
not captured by the definition of ‘‘access
stimulation,’’ and thus, is not subject to
those rules.
4. Recent complaint activity suggests
that much of the post-USF/ICC
Transformation Order access arbitrage
activity specifically involves LECs that
use centralized equal access (CEA)
providers to connect to IXCs. CEA
providers are a specialized type of
intermediate access provider that were
formed in the 1980s to implement long
distance equal access obligations
(permitting end users to use 1+ dialing
PO 00000
Frm 00041
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
30629
to reach the IXC of their choice) and to
aggregate traffic for connection between
rural incumbent LECs and other
networks, particularly those of IXCs.
There are currently three CEA
providers, and the LECs that use them
(subtending LECs) have traditionally
been reliant on CEA providers for this
equal access implementation as well as
traffic measurement and billing.
II. Discussion
5. We propose solutions to the
persistent, costly, and inefficient access
stimulation arbitrage scheme described
here and seek comment on how to
prevent other types of arbitrage. We are
mindful of the fact that practices adjust
to regulatory change; therefore we invite
comment on how to avoid introducing
incentives for new types of arbitrage to
arise.
A. Requiring Access-Stimulating LECs
Either To Be Financially Responsible for
Calls Delivered to Their Networks or To
Accept Direct Connections
6. To rid the ICC system of the
inefficiencies caused by access
stimulation relating to intermediate
access providers, we propose to require
access-stimulating LECs to choose either
to: (i) Bear the financial responsibility
for the delivery of terminating traffic to
their end office, or functional
equivalent, or; (ii) accept direct
connections from either the IXC or an
intermediate access provider of the
IXC’s choice.
7. Revised Financial Responsibility.
We seek comment on the first prong of
our proposal and the impact it will have
on access stimulation schemes. Under
this prong, an access-stimulating LEC
that does not offer direct connections to
IXCs would bear all financial
responsibility for applicable
intermediate access provider
terminating charges normally assessed
to an IXC (from the point of indirect
interconnection to the accessstimulating LEC’s end office or
functional equivalent), and would be
prohibited from assessing transport
charges for any portion of transport
between the intermediate access
provider and the LEC’s end office or
functional equivalent that the LEC,
itself, provides. What are the advantages
of placing the financial responsibility
for delivery of traffic to its end office,
or functional equivalent, on the accessstimulating LEC? Are there
disadvantages?
8. What implementation issues does
this part of our proposal raise? What
steps would intermediate access
providers need to take to bill accessstimulating LECs for terminating access
E:\FR\FM\29JNP1.SGM
29JNP1
30630
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 126 / Friday, June 29, 2018 / Proposed Rules
path and the carrier providing end office
access service.’’ We seek comment on
the use of this definition in this context.
Does it adequately capture the types of
intermediate access providers currently
benefiting from access stimulation
schemes? Is it too narrow or too broad?
10. Direct Connection. Commenters
have argued that the volume of traffic
bound for access-stimulating LECs
justifies direct connections, but allege
that access-stimulating LECs currently
refuse to accept such connections.
Direct connections do not pass through
intermediate switches and are offered
on a capacity basis at monthly-recurring
rates, as opposed to a per-MOU rate. If
there is a sufficient volume of traffic, the
monthly charges for direct connections
can often be substantially lower than
per-MOU rates for an equivalent amount
of traffic. As the second prong of our
proposal, we propose to provide access-
stimulating LECs the option to offer to
connect directly to the IXC or an
intermediate access provider of the
IXC’s choice as an alternative to bearing
financial responsibility for intermediate
access provider charges and ceasing to
bill their own transport charges. Under
this proposal, IXCs would have the
option of selecting an intermediate
access provider that would bill the IXC
for transport to the access-stimulating
LEC on a dedicated basis. We seek
comment on this proposal and on how
best to implement it. We note that as a
result of this election, an IXC would
have the choice to connect with an
access-stimulating LEC directly or
indirectly through the LEC’s existing
intermediate access provider or another
IXC directly connecting to the accessstimulating LEC.
11. For direct connections between an
IXC (or an intermediate access provider
of the IXC’s choosing) and an accessstimulating LEC to be established, not
only must the access-stimulating LEC be
willing and able to accept direct
connections, but arrangements need to
be made between the IXCs seeking to
avail themselves of such connections
and the LEC. If we adopt the approach
we propose today, how long should we
give existing access-stimulating LECs to
indicate their willingness to accept
direct connections and how long should
we give them to implement those direct
connections? How detailed a timeline
should we adopt for this process?
Should we adopt rules regarding the
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:09 Jun 28, 2018
Jkt 244001
PO 00000
Frm 00042
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
E:\FR\FM\29JNP1.SGM
29JNP1
EP29JN18.009
sradovich on DSK3GMQ082PROD with PROPOSALS
and to not bill IXCs? How much time do
access-stimulating LECs and
intermediate access providers need to
make modifications necessary to
accomplish this proposed change in
financial responsibility? We propose to
require carriers to come into compliance
with these requirements within 45 days
of the effective date of any revised rule.
Is that timeframe sufficient? For
example, is it possible to implement
necessary billing system changes within
that time frame? We similarly propose
to require any carriers that newly
qualify as access-stimulating LECs to
come into compliance with these
requirements within 45 days of such
qualification.
9. For purposes of this proposal, we
propose to define ‘‘intermediate access
provider’’ as ‘‘any entity that carries or
processes traffic at any point between
the final interexchange carrier in a call
sradovich on DSK3GMQ082PROD with PROPOSALS
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 126 / Friday, June 29, 2018 / Proposed Rules
conduct of any negotiations for direct
connections? For example, should we
adopt a timeframe within which
negotiations must be concluded before
the LEC must assume financial
responsibility for the delivery of traffic
or the impasse submitted to arbitration?
Similarly, if, at some later date, an
access-stimulating LEC decides to offer
direct connections, what process should
the access-stimulating LEC need to
follow to cease bearing the financial
obligation for the intermediate access
providers’ charges? How should we
address LECs that meet the definition of
access-stimulating LEC after adoption of
our rules? If they chose to offer direct
connections, what time frame should we
provide for making and implementing
that decision?
12. We propose to adopt a rule that
makes clear that allowing accessstimulating LECs to accept direct
connection as a means of not bearing
financial responsibility for intermediate
access provider charges does not carry
with it an obligation for such LECs to
extend their networks absent a request
and an independent obligation to do so.
Is this a reasonable limitation? Are there
any other limitations or exceptions we
should apply? Are there other rules we
should adopt to help providers
implement the option to accept direct
connections if a provider makes that
choice? For example, because IXCs are
not currently directly connected to
access-stimulating LECs in the scenario
to which our proposal applies, a thirdparty vendor may need to connect the
two networks via dedicated transport
such as, perhaps, the current
intermediate access provider. Are there
any rules that we should adopt to
facilitate such arrangements?
13. One result of permitting accessstimulating LECs that subtend CEA
providers to connect with IXCs directly
(or an intermediate access provider of
an IXC’s choice) would be to end the
‘‘mandatory use’’ policy applicable to
some CEA providers, at least with
respect to access-stimulating LECs.
Historically, this mandatory use policy
has permitted the CEA providers in
Iowa and South Dakota to require IXCs
to connect to LECs that subtend the CEA
provider indirectly through the CEA
provider’s tandem switch rather than
indirectly through another intermediate
access provider or directly to the
subtending LEC. In initially permitting
this practice almost thirty years ago, the
Commission concluded that it ‘‘[did] not
believe that the mandatory termination
requirement for interstate traffic is
unreasonable or differs substantially
from the normal way access is provided,
as both an originating and terminating
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:09 Jun 28, 2018
Jkt 244001
service by the local exchange
company.’’
14. It appears that access stimulation,
particularly when practiced by
competitive LECs, which were formed
well after CEA providers were
established, presents a reasonable
circumstance for departing from the
policy of permitting mandatory use
requirements because delivery of such
traffic, particularly in the pertinent
volumes, was not the purpose for which
CEA providers were formed. We seek
comment on this assumption, and on
the impact of this proposal on CEA
providers, on the LECs that subtend
CEA providers, and on the customers of
such subtending LECs. For example, to
the extent that creating the opportunity
for access-stimulation traffic to bypass
CEA providers threatens the viability of
CEA providers, we seek comment on
whether and how this potential effect
should be addressed. Are there other
companies that can perform the
traditional functions of CEA providers,
including equal access implementation
and traffic measurement and billing?
Recognizing that most states do not have
CEA providers, are there ways that
equal access and traffic identification
and measurement are handled by small
LECs in those states that can inform our
decision making in this proceeding?
15. Notice Requirement. We propose
to require access-stimulating LECs to
notify affected IXCs and intermediate
access providers of their intent to accept
financial responsibility for calls
delivered to their networks or to accept
direct connections from IXCs or
intermediate access providers of the
IXCs’ choosing. Should we also require
the access-stimulating LEC to provide
public, written notice of its choice to the
Commission? Should we provide
specific requirements regarding the form
and content of such notice? For
example, should we require an accessstimulating LEC to accept direct
connections at current points of
interconnection (POI) with intermediate
access providers, as well as at the LECs’
end office, and to provide notice of
those locations? Or, should we allow an
access-stimulating LEC to choose where
to provide POIs and to specify those
locations in its notice? Should accessstimulating LECs also provide notice to
the Commission and state commissions
of their choice to accept direct
connections and of the location of their
POIs? To ensure that the investment
made by an IXC to extend its network
to directly interconnect with an accessstimulating LEC is not stranded, should
an access-stimulating LEC be prohibited
from ending its election of direct
connections once made? Should such a
PO 00000
Frm 00043
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
30631
prohibition be permanent or for a
specified period of time?
16. Impact of this Proposal. We seek
comment on the costs and benefits of
our proposal. To what extent will our
two-pronged proposal alleviate market
distortions created by the ability of
access-stimulating LECs to bill for
switched transport services at rates that
our rules have not required to be
reduced below 2011 interstate levels?
Will the incentives created by our
proposal for access-stimulating LECs to
accept direct connections (to avoid
bearing intermediate access provider
charges imposed by a provider of the
access-stimulating LEC’s choosing)
alleviate the problem of IXCs paying
relatively-high tandem-switched
transport rates by giving IXCs more
options to reach end users?
17. How will our proposal affect
incentives for carriers to migrate their
services to IP? To what extent do parties
expect that direct connections would be
provided in time division multiplexed
(TDM) format rather than IP? Are there
circumstances under which an accessstimulating LEC should be required,
upon request, to interconnect using IP
rather than TDM and bear any costs
necessary to do so? Are calls bound for
high call volume service providers
ultimately converted to IP for delivery?
Would requiring IP interconnection
obviate the need to convert TDM traffic
to IP for delivery?
18. NTCA et al. Proposal. NTCA et al.
has recommended that we adopt rules
similar to the first prong of our
proposal, but without providing an
access-stimulating LEC the option of
electing to accept direct connections as
a means of avoiding bearing
intermediate access provider charges.
Under the NTCA et al. proposal, within
45 days of the effective date of the
implementing rules, access-stimulating
LECs would be required to revise their
tariffs to remove any terminating
interstate tandem switching and tandem
transport charges of their own and also
begin to assume financial responsibility
for all intermediate switched access
provider interstate tandem switching
and transport charges for traffic bound
for such access-stimulating LECs. The
NTCA et al. proposal would also require
access-stimulating LECs to provide
written notice to all affected providers,
including intermediate access providers,
of the substance of these tariff revisions
at the time that such tariff revisions are
filed, as well as the fact that such
access-stimulating LECs will be bearing
financial responsibility for pertinent
intermediate switched access provider
interstate tandem switching and
transport charges.
E:\FR\FM\29JNP1.SGM
29JNP1
30632
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 126 / Friday, June 29, 2018 / Proposed Rules
sradovich on DSK3GMQ082PROD with PROPOSALS
19. Although the NTCA et al. proposal
does not preclude an access-stimulating
LEC from avoiding incurring
intermediate access provider charges by
beginning to accept direct connections,
it also does not provide IXCs any
incentive to accept offers of direct
connection from such LECs. By
permitting access-stimulating LECs to
elect to accept direct connections, our
proposal seeks to provide a formal
means by which access-stimulating
LECs may eventually avoid incurring
intermediate access provider charges.
We seek comment on the NTCA et al.
proposal both as an independent
proposal and also as it relates to our
proposal above.
20. CenturyLink Proposal.
CenturyLink suggests that we consider
an approach similar to our proposal, but
with broader applicability. Rather than
focusing on access-stimulating LECs,
CenturyLink recommends shifting
financial responsibility to any LEC that
declines to accept a request for direct
interconnection for the purpose of
terminating access traffic. We seek
comment on this recommendation.
What would be the impact of such an
approach on the affected companies and
their customers?
B. Requiring All Access-Stimulating
LECs To Transition to Bill-and-Keep
21. If we do not adopt rules requiring
access-stimulating LECs to either choose
to accept financial responsibility for the
delivery of calls or to accept direct
connections, should we reduce all
terminating tandem switching, common
transport, and tandem-switched
transport rate elements for access
stimulators to bill-and-keep? Moving
these access charges to bill-and-keep
would be consistent with our
overarching goals of discouraging
arbitrage, in particular access
stimulation, and ultimately
transitioning all traffic to bill-and-keep.
It would also be consistent with the
Commission’s finding in the USF/ICC
Transformation Order that with respect
to terminating traffic, the LEC’s end user
is the cost causer and therefore the LEC
should look first to its subscribers to
recover the costs of it network. To what
extent would this approach resolve the
access arbitrage concerns identified in
this NPRM? We also seek comment on
how this approach fits with the other
proposals in this NPRM. For example, if
we reduce all terminating access charges
to bill-and-keep is there any remaining
incentive for carriers to stimulate
traffic? We also seek comment on any
implementation issues or concerns
related to the proposal. Should we
provide for a transition period to bill-
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:09 Jun 28, 2018
Jkt 244001
and-keep for access stimulators? If so,
how long should the transition last and
what steps should it include?
22. We also seek comment on whether
to require an access-stimulating LEC to
transition its dedicated transport and
originating rates to bill-and-keep. The
only potential access arbitrage scheme
of which we are aware regarding
originating access concerns 8YY traffic,
which we leave for separate
consideration. Outside the 8YY context,
are there arbitrage schemes involving
originating access about which we
should be concerned? Can they be
addressed by a transition to bill-andkeep or by other proposals in this
NPRM?
C. Defining Access Stimulation
23. Given evidence that access
stimulation schemes are still being
perpetrated notwithstanding our
existing rules, we seek comment on
whether, and if so how, to revise the
current definition of access stimulation
to more accurately and effectively target
harmful access stimulation practices.
What has been the impact of the current
definition over the last seven years? Has
it proved effective at identifying actors
that are distorting the ICC system for
their own gain? If not, how can we
revise the definition to more accurately
identify these types of harmful
practices? Should we, for example,
modify the ratios or triggers in the
definition? If so, how should those
ratios or triggers be modified? Should
we adopt triggers that relate to the
stimulation of tandem and transport
services? If so, what should those
triggers be? Is the current revenue
sharing agreement requirement in our
rules sufficiently broad or should it be
revised, and if so how? Or, should we
remove the revenue sharing portion of
the definition, because access
stimulation seems to be occurring in
some instances even in the absence of
revenue sharing? Do commenters
believe that revenue sharing alone is an
indication of access stimulation? If so,
should we revise our rules so that the
existence of a revenue sharing
agreement triggers the access
stimulation rule? How will we know if
parties are engaged in revenue sharing?
Should we require these parties to selfreport? If so, we seek comment on how
to implement a self-reporting
requirement.
24. Alternatively, based on parties’
experience with our existing access
stimulation rules, is there reason to find
that access stimulation itself is unjust
and unreasonable because of the
imposition of excess charges on IXCs,
wireless carriers, and their customers?
PO 00000
Frm 00044
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
Or, is there a subset of such activities
that we should separately identify as
unlawful?
25. To address specific concerns
identified in the record, commenters
should also consider the extent to which
the access stimulation definition should
be revised to address intermediate
access providers. Do intermediate access
providers that are not engaged in access
stimulation as defined in our current
rules nevertheless benefit from access
stimulation schemes? To remove
incentives for intermediate access
providers to enable access arbitrage
schemes, aside from the proposals
discussed above, should we adopt new
access stimulation rules, or modify our
existing rules, to apply specifically to
intermediate access providers? Would
doing so be unduly burdensome to
intermediate access providers or small
LECs who subtend them? Are there
technical obstacles that would make it
infeasible for intermediate access
providers to comply with the
Commission’s current, or any modified,
access stimulation rules? Would a
requirement that access-stimulating
subtending LECs notify the intermediate
access provider that they are engaged in
access stimulation and identify the
traffic that is being stimulated provide
a practical solution?
D. Addressing Other Arbitrage Schemes,
and Alternative Approaches to
Arbitrage
26. The record indicates the existence
of at least three other types of arbitrage
schemes. We seek comment on the
prevalence and impact of these types of
schemes described in more detail below.
Will any of the rules we propose today
help retard these schemes? Are there
other rules we should adopt to prevent
these schemes?
27. First, parties describe an access
arbitrage scheme involving a revenue
sharing or other type of agreement
between an intermediate access
provider and a terminating carrier that
may not meet the definition of access
stimulation under our rules, such as a
Commercial Mobile Radio Service
(CMRS) carrier. CMRS carriers are
prohibited from tariffing access charges.
However, intermediate access providers
that transport traffic from an IXC to
CMRS carriers can charge for access
services through filed tariffs or
negotiated agreements. Some IXCs claim
that certain CMRS carriers that
previously offered direct connections
between their networks and the IXCs’
networks have begun to use
intermediate access providers to
terminate their traffic from IXCs, to reap
the benefit of alleged revenue sharing
E:\FR\FM\29JNP1.SGM
29JNP1
sradovich on DSK3GMQ082PROD with PROPOSALS
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 126 / Friday, June 29, 2018 / Proposed Rules
agreements with the intermediate access
providers. Should we adopt rules that
discourage all revenue sharing
agreements between terminating
providers and intermediate access
providers? If a terminating provider
requires that some or all traffic be
routed through an intermediate access
provider, should we require the
terminating provider to pay the
intermediate access provider’s charges?
Or are there instances where it is most
efficient or beneficial in other ways for
a carrier to require traffic be routed
through an intermediate access
provider? What would be the costs and
benefits of requiring a terminating
provider that requires the use of a
specific intermediate access provider to
pay the intermediate access provider’s
charges? And would the cost-benefit
analysis change if we focused any such
rules on large terminating providers—
i.e., those with 100,000 or more ‘‘lines’’
at the holding company level?
28. Second, because LECs and
intermediate access providers receive
greater compensation from IXCs the
further the LEC or intermediate access
provider carries the traffic to reach a
POI with the IXC, some commenters
allege that LECs have changed their POI
with IXCs for the sole purpose of
artificially inflating their per-MOU, permile transport rates and revenue. This
scheme is often referred to as mileage
pumping. Shortly after the USF/ICC
Transformation Order, the Commission
released an order addressing this
practice finding such network changes
were merely sham arrangements and
that the LECs did not have the unilateral
right under their tariffs to make such
changes. Nevertheless, allegations of
mileage pumping continue. We seek
comment on the prevalence of this
practice, its impact in the market, and
the likely effect of the rules proposed in
this NPRM on this concern. What more
can we do to prevent these practices?
29. Third, some commenters raise
concerns about the addition of
superfluous network facilities for which
the LEC can bill switched access
charges, but the rates for which are not
subject to the current transition to billand-keep. This practice is sometimes
referred to as ‘‘daisy chaining.’’ This
practice may inefficiently inflate permile charges and insert unnecessary
facilities to justify assessment of
additional rate elements, such as remote
switches that subtend end offices. What
actions can we take to prevent daisy
chaining?
30. Would the CenturyLink suggestion
of shifting financial responsibility to
LECs that decline to accept direct
connections eliminate or reduce the
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:09 Jun 28, 2018
Jkt 244001
three types of inefficient routing
schemes described above? Even if an
IXC chose not to seek a direct
connection, would the risk of IXCs
seeking direct connections provide a
disciplining counterweight to some
providers’ incentives to engage in
mileage pumping or daisy-chaining?
What would be the impact on affected
parties?
E. Other Issues
31. We recognize that any action we
take to address access arbitrage may
affect the costs to carriers and their
customers and the choices they make, as
they provide and receive
telecommunications services.
Consumers that enjoy high call volume
services could be affected by regulatory
adjustments targeting arbitrage. Are
there efficiencies that are in the public’s
interest in what some describe as
arbitrage? Would addressing the
arbitrage described here unfairly
advantage any particular competitor or
class of competitors? If so, are there
alternative means to address the
arbitrage issues described here and
presented in the record? How would the
changes proposed herein affect small
businesses?
32. In the USF/ICC Transformation
Order, the Commission considered
direct costs imposed on consumers by
arbitrage schemes. The Commission also
found that access stimulation diverts
‘‘capital away from more productive
uses such as broadband deployment.’’
We believe this continues to be true. Are
there additional, more-current data
available to estimate the annual cost of
arbitrage schemes to companies, long
distance rate payers, and consumers in
general? Likewise, are there data
available to quantify the resources being
diverted from infrastructure investment
because of arbitrage schemes? To what
degree are consumers indirectly affected
by potentially inefficient networking
and cost recovery due to current
regulations and the exploitation of those
regulations? Are there other costs or
benefits we should consider?
F. Legal Authority
33. The proposals in this NPRM,
targeted to address the particular issues
described in the record, continue the
work the Commission began in the USF/
ICC Transformation Order to stop
economically wasteful arbitrage activity
and the damage it causes in
telecommunications markets. Therefore,
we rely on the legal authority the
Commission set forth in the USF/ICC
Transformation Order, as support for
modifications to rules we propose in
this NPRM. The Commission made clear
PO 00000
Frm 00045
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
30633
that its rules to address access arbitrage
would result in interstate access rates
‘‘consistent with section 201(b) of the
Act.’’ The Commission likewise found
that ‘‘[o]ur statutory authority to
implement bill-and-keep as the default
framework for the exchange of traffic
with LECs flows directly from sections
251(b)(5) and 201(b) of the Act.’’ We
seek comment on whether additional
statutory authority is available, or
necessary, to support the actions
proposed here.
III. Rule Revisions
34. We seek comment on the rule
changes proposed at the end of this
document. What, if any, other rule
additions or modifications should we
make to codify these proposals? Are
there any conforming rule changes that
commenters consider necessary? For
example, we intend for any rules that
we adopt to apply not only to interstate
traffic, but also intrastate traffic. Do our
proposed rules adequately address this?
Are there any conflicts or
inconsistencies between existing rules
and those proposed herein? We ask
commenters to provide any other
proposed actions and rule additions or
modifications we should consider to
address the access arbitrage schemes
described in this NPRM including
updates to any relevant comments or
proposals made in response to the USF/
ICC Transformation FNPRM, 76 FR
78383.
IV. Procedural Matters
35. Filing Instructions. Pursuant to
§§ 1.415 and 1.419 of the Commission’s
rules, 47 CFR 1.415, 1.419, interested
parties may file comments and reply
comments on or before the dates
indicated on the first page of this
document. Comments may be filed
using the Commission’s Electronic
Comment Filing System (ECFS). See
Electronic Filing of Documents in
Rulemaking Proceedings, 63 FR 24121
(1998).
• Electronic Filers: Comments may be
filed electronically using the internet
by accessing the ECFS: https://
www.fcc.gov/ecfs/
• Paper Filers: Parties who choose to
file by paper must file an original and
one copy of each filing. If more than
one docket or rulemaking number
appears in the caption of this
proceeding, filers must submit two
additional copies for each additional
docket or rulemaking number.
Filings can be sent by hand or
messenger delivery, by commercial
overnight courier, or by first-class or
overnight U.S. Postal Service mail. All
E:\FR\FM\29JNP1.SGM
29JNP1
sradovich on DSK3GMQ082PROD with PROPOSALS
30634
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 126 / Friday, June 29, 2018 / Proposed Rules
filings must be addressed to the
Commission’s Secretary, Office of the
Secretary, Federal Communications
Commission.
• All hand-delivered or messengerdelivered paper filings for the
Commission’s Secretary must be
delivered to FCC Headquarters at 445
12th St. SW, Room TW–A325,
Washington, DC 20554. The filing hours
are 8:00 a.m. to 7:00 p.m. All hand
deliveries must be held together with
rubber bands or fasteners. Any
envelopes and boxes must be disposed
of before entering the building.
• Commercial overnight mail (other
than U.S. Postal Service Express Mail
and Priority Mail) must be sent to 9050
Junction Drive, Annapolis Junction, MD
20701.
• U.S. Postal Service first-class,
Express, and Priority mail must be
addressed to 445 12th Street SW,
Washington, DC 20554.
36. People with Disabilities. To
request materials in accessible formats
for people with disabilities (braille,
large print, electronic files, audio
format), send an email to fcc504@fcc.gov
or call the Consumer & Governmental
Affairs Bureau at 202–418–0530 (voice),
202–418–0432 (tty).
37. Ex Parte Requirements. This
proceeding shall be treated as a ‘‘permitbut-disclose’’ proceeding in accordance
with the Commission’s ex parte rules.
Persons making ex parte presentations
must file a copy of any written
presentation or a memorandum
summarizing any oral presentation
within two business days after the
presentation (unless a different deadline
applicable to the Sunshine period
applies). Persons making oral ex parte
presentations are reminded that
memoranda summarizing the
presentation must: (1) List all persons
attending or otherwise participating in
the meeting at which the ex parte
presentation was made; and (2)
summarize all data presented and
arguments made during the
presentation. If the presentation
consisted in whole or in part of the
presentation of data or arguments
already reflected in the presenter’s
written comments, memoranda, or other
filings in the proceeding, the presenter
may provide citations to such data or
arguments in his or her prior comments,
memoranda, or other filings (specifying
the relevant page and/or paragraph
numbers where such data or arguments
can be found) in lieu of summarizing
them in the memorandum. Documents
shown or given to Commission staff
during ex parte meetings are deemed to
be written ex parte presentations and
must be filed consistent with Rule
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:09 Jun 28, 2018
Jkt 244001
1.1206(b). In proceedings governed by
Rule 1.49(f) or for which the
Commission has made available a
method of electronic filing, written ex
parte presentations and memoranda
summarizing oral ex parte
presentations, and all attachments
thereto, must be filed through the
electronic comment filing system
available for that proceeding, and must
be filed in their native format (e.g., .doc,
.xml, .ppt, searchable .pdf). Participants
in this proceeding should familiarize
themselves with the Commission’s ex
parte rules.
38. Paperwork Reduction Act
Analysis. This document contains
proposed new and modified information
collection requirements. The
Commission, as part of its continuing
effort to reduce paperwork burdens,
invites the general public and the Office
of Management and Budget to comment
on the information collection
requirements contained in this
document, as required by the Paperwork
Reduction Act of 1995, Public Law 104–
13. In addition, pursuant to the Small
Business Paperwork Relief Act of 2002,
Public Law 107–198, see 44 U.S.C.
3506(c)(4), we seek specific comment on
how we might further reduce the
information collection burden for small
business concerns with fewer than 25
employees.
39. Initial Regulatory Flexibility Act
Analysis. Pursuant to the Regulatory
Flexibility Act (RFA), we have prepared
an Initial Regulatory Flexibility
Analysis (IRFA) of the possible
significant economic impact on small
entities of the policies and actions
considered in this NPRM. The
Commission prepared an IRFA to
accompany the first Further Notice of
Proposed Rulemaking in this docket,
USF/ICC Transformation FNPRM. The
questions asked in this NPRM are
different than those the Commission
sought comment on previously.
Therefore, we have prepared a new
IRFA to reflect the substance of this
NPRM. The text of the IRFA is set forth
in section V of this document. Written
public comments are requested on this
IRFA. Comments must be identified as
responses to the IRFA and must be filed
by the deadlines for comments on the
NPRM. The Commission’s Consumer
and Governmental Affairs Bureau,
Reference Information Center, will send
a copy of the NPRM, including the
IRFA, to the Chief Counsel for Advocacy
of the Small Business Administration.
40. Contact Person. For further
information about this proceeding,
please contact Edward Krachmer, FCC
Wireline Competition Bureau, Pricing
Policy Division, Room 5–A230, 445 12th
PO 00000
Frm 00046
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
Street SW, Washington, DC 20554, (202)
418–1525, Edward.Krachmer@fcc.gov.
V. Initial Regulatory Flexibility
Analysis
41. As required by the Regulatory
Flexibility Act of 1980, as amended
(RFA), we have prepared this Initial
Regulatory Flexibility Analysis (IRFA)
of the possible significant economic
impact on a substantial number of small
entities by the policies and rules
proposed in this Notice of Proposed
Rulemaking (NPRM). We request
written public comments on this IRFA.
Comments must be identified as
responses to the IRFA and must be filed
by the deadlines for comments provided
on the first page of the NPRM. We will
send a copy of the NPRM, including this
IRFA, to the Chief Counsel for Advocacy
of the Small Business Administration
(SBA). In addition, the NPRM and IRFA
(or summaries thereof) will be
published in the Federal Register.
A. Need for, and Objective of, the
Proposed Rules
42. In the USF/ICC Transformation
FNPRM, the Commission sought
comment on additional steps to
implement the bill-and-keep regime as
well as possible communications
network definitional changes, the
appropriate recovery mechanisms going
forward and VoIP and IP-to-IP related
intercarrier compensation issues. In this
NPRM we propose to adopt rules to
address access arbitrage schemes that
persist despite previous Commission
action. We propose to adopt rules to
give access-stimulating LECs two
choices about how they connect to IXCs.
First, an access-stimulating LEC can
choose to be financially responsible for
calls delivered to its networks so it,
rather than IXCs, pays for the delivery
of calls to its end office or the functional
equivalent. Or, second, instead of
accepting this financial responsibility,
an access-stimulating LEC can choose to
accept direct connections from either
the IXC or an intermediate access
provider of the IXC’s choosing. In the
alternative, we seek comment on
moving all traffic bound for an accessstimulating LEC to bill-and-keep. The
NPRM also seeks comment on potential
revisions to the definition of access
stimulation, in particular to address
intermediate access providers. The
record in this proceeding suggests
additional access arbitrage activities are
occurring, including: (1) Use of
intermediate access providers by
Commercial Mobile Radio Carriers; (2)
mileage pumping; and (3) daisy
chaining. Comment is sought on how
best to address these activities. The
E:\FR\FM\29JNP1.SGM
29JNP1
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 126 / Friday, June 29, 2018 / Proposed Rules
NPRM seeks comment on the costs and
benefits of these proposals.
sradovich on DSK3GMQ082PROD with PROPOSALS
B. Legal Basis
43. The legal basis for any action that
may be taken pursuant to this NPRM is
contained in sections 1, 2, 4(i), 201–206,
214, 218–220, 251, 252, 254, 256, 303(r),
and 403 of the Communications Act of
1934, as amended, 47 U.S.C. 151, 152,
154(i), 201–206, 214, 218–220, 251, 252,
254, 256, 303(r), and 403.
C. Description and Estimate of the
Number of Small Entities to Which the
Proposed Rules Will Apply
44. The RFA directs agencies to
provide a description of, and where
feasible, an estimate of the number of
small entities that may be affected by
the proposed rule revisions, if adopted.
The RFA generally defines the term
‘‘small entity’’ as having the same
meaning as the terms ‘‘small business,’’
‘‘small organization,’’ and ‘‘small
governmental jurisdiction.’’ In addition,
the term ‘‘small business’’ has the same
meaning as the term ‘‘small-business
concern’’ under the Small Business Act.
A ‘‘small-business concern’’ is one
which: (1) Is independently owned and
operated; (2) is not dominant in its field
of operation; and (3) satisfies any
additional criteria established by the
SBA.
45. Small Businesses, Small
Organizations, Small Governmental
Jurisdictions. Our actions, over time,
may affect small entities that are not
easily categorized at present. We
therefore describe here, at the outset,
three comprehensive small entity size
standards that could be directly affected
herein. First, while there are industry
specific size standards for small
businesses that are used in the
regulatory flexibility analysis, according
to data from the SBA’s Office of
Advocacy, in general a small business is
an independent business having fewer
than 500 employees. These types of
small businesses represent 99.9% of all
businesses in the United States which
translates to 28.8 million businesses.
Next, the type of small entity described
as a ‘‘small organization’’ is generally
‘‘any not-for-profit enterprise which is
independently owned and operated and
is not dominant in its field.’’
Nationwide, as of August 2016, there
were approximately 356,494 small
organizations based on registration and
tax data filed by nonprofits with the
Internal Revenue Service (IRS). Finally,
the small entity described as a ‘‘small
governmental jurisdiction’’ is defined
generally as ‘‘governments of cities,
towns, townships, villages, school
districts, or special districts, with a
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:09 Jun 28, 2018
Jkt 244001
population of less than fifty thousand.’’
U.S. Census Bureau data from the 2012
Census of Governments indicate that
there were 90,056 local governmental
jurisdictions consisting of general
purpose governments and special
purpose governments in the United
States. Of this number there were 37,
132 General purpose governments
(county, municipal and town or
township) with populations of less than
50,000 and 12,184 Special purpose
governments (independent school
districts and special districts) with
populations of less than 50,000. The
2012 U.S. Census Bureau data for most
types of governments in the local
government category show that the
majority of these governments have
populations of less than 50,000. Based
on this data we estimate that at least
49,316 local government jurisdictions
fall in the category of ‘‘small
governmental jurisdictions.’’
46. Wired Telecommunications
Carriers. The U.S. Census Bureau
defines this industry as ‘‘establishments
primarily engaged in operating and/or
providing access to transmission
facilities and infrastructure that they
own and/or lease for the transmission of
voice, data, text, sound, and video using
wired communications networks.
Transmission facilities may be based on
a single technology or a combination of
technologies. Establishments in this
industry use the wired
telecommunications network facilities
that they operate to provide a variety of
services, such as wired telephony
services, including VoIP services, wired
(cable) audio and video programming
distribution, and wired broadband
internet services. By exception,
establishments providing satellite
television distribution services using
facilities and infrastructure that they
operate are included in this industry.’’
The SBA has developed a small
business size standard for Wired
Telecommunications Carriers, which
consists of all such companies having
1,500 or fewer employees. Census data
for 2012 show that there were 3,117
firms that operated that year. Of this
total, 3,083 operated with fewer than
1,000 employees. Thus, under this size
standard, the majority of firms in this
industry can be considered small.
47. Local Exchange Carriers (LECs).
Neither the Commission nor the SBA
has developed a size standard for small
businesses specifically applicable to
local exchange services. The closest
applicable NAICS Code category is
Wired Telecommunications Carriers and
under the applicable SBA size standard,
such a business is small if it has 1,500
or fewer employees. U.S. Census data
PO 00000
Frm 00047
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
30635
for 2012 show that there were 3,117
firms that operated that year. Of that
total, 3,083 operated with fewer than
1,000 employees. Thus under this
category and the associated size
standard, the Commission estimates that
the majority of local exchange carriers
are small entities.
48. Incumbent LECs. Neither the
Commission nor the SBA has developed
a small business size standard
specifically for incumbent local
exchange services. The closest
applicable NAICS Code category is
Wired Telecommunications Carriers as
defined above. Under that size standard,
such a business is small if it has 1,500
or fewer employees. According to
Commission data, 3,117 firms operated
in that year. Of this total, 3,083 operated
with fewer than 1,000 employees.
Consequently, the Commission
estimates that most providers of
incumbent local exchange service are
small businesses that may be affected by
the rules and policies adopted. Three
hundred and seven (307) Incumbent
Local Exchange Carriers reported that
they were incumbent local exchange
service providers. Of this total, an
estimated 1,006 have 1,500 or fewer
employees.
49. Competitive Local Exchange
Carriers (Competitive LECs),
Competitive Access Providers (CAPs),
Shared-Tenant Service Providers, and
Other Local Service Providers. Neither
the Commission nor the SBA has
developed a small business size
standard specifically for these service
providers. The appropriate NAICS Code
category is Wired Telecommunications
Carriers, as defined above. Under that
size standard, such a business is small
if it has 1,500 or fewer employees. U.S.
Census data for 2012 indicate that 3,117
firms operated during that year. Of that
number, 3,083 operated with fewer than
1,000 employees. Based on this data, the
Commission concludes that the majority
of Competitive LECS, CAPs, SharedTenant Service Providers, and Other
Local Service Providers, are small
entities. According to Commission data,
1,442 carriers reported that they were
engaged in the provision of either
competitive local exchange services or
competitive access provider services. Of
these 1,442 carriers, an estimated 1,256
have 1,500 or fewer employees. In
addition, 17 carriers have reported that
they are Shared-Tenant Service
Providers, and all 17 are estimated to
have 1,500 or fewer employees. Also, 72
carriers have reported that they are
Other Local Service Providers. Of this
total, 70 have 1,500 or fewer employees.
Consequently, based on internally
researched FCC data, the Commission
E:\FR\FM\29JNP1.SGM
29JNP1
sradovich on DSK3GMQ082PROD with PROPOSALS
30636
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 126 / Friday, June 29, 2018 / Proposed Rules
estimates that most providers of
competitive local exchange service,
competitive access providers, SharedTenant Service Providers, and Other
Local Service Providers are small
entities.
50. We have included small
incumbent LECs in this present RFA
analysis. As noted above, a ‘‘small
business’’ under the RFA is one that,
inter alia, meets the pertinent small
business size standard (e.g., a telephone
communications business having 1,500
or fewer employees), and ‘‘is not
dominant in its field of operation.’’ The
SBA’s Office of Advocacy contends that,
for RFA purposes, small incumbent
LECs are not dominant in their field of
operation because any such dominance
is not ‘‘national’’ in scope. We have
therefore included small incumbent
LECs in this RFA analysis, although we
emphasize that this RFA action has no
effect on Commission analyses and
determinations in other, non-RFA
contexts.
51. Interexchange Carriers (IXCs).
Neither the Commission nor the SBA
has developed a definition for
Interexchange Carriers. The closest
NAICS Code category is Wired
Telecommunications Carriers as defined
above. The applicable size standard
under SBA rules is that such a business
is small if it has 1,500 or fewer
employees. U.S. Census data for 2012
indicates that 3,117 firms operated
during that year. Of that number, 3,083
operated with fewer than 1,000
employees. According to internally
developed Commission data, 359
companies reported that their primary
telecommunications service activity was
the provision of interexchange services.
Of this total, an estimated 317 have
1,500 or fewer employees.
Consequently, the Commission
estimates that the majority of IXCs are
small entities.
52. Local Resellers. The SBA has
developed a small business size
standard for the category of
Telecommunications Resellers. The
Telecommunications Resellers industry
comprises establishments engaged in
purchasing access and network capacity
from owners and operators of
telecommunications networks and
reselling wired and wireless
telecommunications services (except
satellite) to businesses and households.
Establishments in this industry resell
telecommunications; they do not
operate transmission facilities and
infrastructure. Mobile virtual network
operators (MVNOs) are included in this
industry. Under that size standard, such
a business is small if it has 1,500 or
fewer employees. Census data for 2012
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:09 Jun 28, 2018
Jkt 244001
show that 1,341 firms provided resale
services during that year. Of that
number, all operated with fewer than
1,000 employees. Thus, under this
category and the associated small
business size standard, the majority of
these resellers can be considered small
entities.
53. Toll Resellers. The Commission
has not developed a definition for Toll
Resellers. The closest NAICS Code
Category is Telecommunications
Resellers. The Telecommunications
Resellers industry comprises
establishments engaged in purchasing
access and network capacity from
owners and operators of
telecommunications networks and
reselling wired and wireless
telecommunications services (except
satellite) to businesses and households.
Establishments in this industry resell
telecommunications; they do not
operate transmission facilities and
infrastructure. Mobile virtual network
operators (MVNOs) are included in this
industry. The SBA has developed a
small business size standard for the
category of Telecommunications
Resellers. Under that size standard, such
a business is small if it has 1,500 or
fewer employees. Census data for 2012
show that 1,341 firms provided resale
services during that year. Of that
number, 1,341 operated with fewer than
1,000 employees. Thus, under this
category and the associated small
business size standard, the majority of
these resellers can be considered small
entities. According to Commission data,
881 carriers have reported that they are
engaged in the provision of toll resale
services. Of this total, an estimated 857
have 1,500 or fewer employees.
Consequently, the Commission
estimates that the majority of toll
resellers are small entities.
54. Other Toll Carriers. Neither the
Commission nor the SBA has developed
a definition for small businesses
specifically applicable to Other Toll
Carriers. This category includes toll
carriers that do not fall within the
categories of interexchange carriers,
operator service providers, prepaid
calling card providers, satellite service
carriers, or toll resellers. The closest
applicable NAICS Code category is for
Wired Telecommunications Carriers as
defined above. Under the applicable
SBA size standard, such a business is
small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees.
Census data for 2012 shows that there
were 3,117 firms that operated that year.
Of this total, 3,083 operated with fewer
than 1,000 employees. Thus, under this
category and the associated small
business size standard, the majority of
Other Toll Carriers can be considered
PO 00000
Frm 00048
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
small. According to internally
developed Commission data, 284
companies reported that their primary
telecommunications service activity was
the provision of other toll carriage. Of
these, an estimated 279 have 1,500 or
fewer employees. Consequently, the
Commission estimates that most Other
Toll Carriers are small entities.
55. Prepaid Calling Card Providers.
The SBA has developed a definition for
small businesses within the category of
Telecommunications Resellers. Under
that SBA definition, such a business is
small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees.
According to the Commission’s Form
499 Filer Database, 500 companies
reported that they were engaged in the
provision of prepaid calling cards. The
Commission does not have data
regarding how many of these 500
companies have 1,500 or fewer
employees. Consequently, the
Commission estimates that there are 500
or fewer prepaid calling card providers
that may be affected by the rules.
56. Wireless Telecommunications
Carriers (except Satellite). This industry
comprises establishments engaged in
operating and maintaining switching
and transmission facilities to provide
communications via the airwaves.
Establishments in this industry have
spectrum licenses and provide services
using that spectrum, such as cellular
services, paging services, wireless
internet access, and wireless video
services. The appropriate size standard
under SBA rules is that such a business
is small if it has 1,500 or fewer
employees. For this industry, U.S.
Census data for 2012 show that there
were 967 firms that operated for the
entire year. Of this total, 955 firms had
employment of 999 or fewer employees
and 12 had employment of 1000
employees or more. Thus under this
category and the associated size
standard, the Commission estimates that
the majority of wireless
telecommunications carriers (except
satellite) are small entities.
57. The Commission’s own data—
available in its Universal Licensing
System—indicate that, as of October 25,
2016, there are 280 Cellular licensees
that may be affected by our actions
today. The Commission does not know
how many of these licensees are small,
as the Commission does not collect that
information for these types of entities.
Similarly, according to internally
developed Commission data, 413
carriers reported that they were engaged
in the provision of wireless telephony,
including cellular service, Personal
Communications Service, and
Specialized Mobile Radio Telephony
services. Of this total, an estimated 261
E:\FR\FM\29JNP1.SGM
29JNP1
sradovich on DSK3GMQ082PROD with PROPOSALS
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 126 / Friday, June 29, 2018 / Proposed Rules
have 1,500 or fewer employees, and 152
have more than 1,500 employees. Thus,
using available data, we estimate that
the majority of wireless firms can be
considered small.
58. Wireless Communications
Services. This service can be used for
fixed, mobile, radiolocation, and digital
audio broadcasting satellite uses. The
Commission defined ‘‘small business’’
for the wireless communications
services (WCS) auction as an entity with
average gross revenues of $40 million
for each of the three preceding years,
and a ‘‘very small business’’ as an entity
with average gross revenues of $15
million for each of the three preceding
years. The SBA has approved these
definitions.
59. Wireless Telephony. Wireless
telephony includes cellular, personal
communications services, and
specialized mobile radio telephony
carriers. As noted, the SBA has
developed a small business size
standard for Wireless
Telecommunications Carriers (except
Satellite). Under the SBA small business
size standard, a business is small if it
has 1,500 or fewer employees.
According to Commission data, 413
carriers reported that they were engaged
in wireless telephony. Of these, an
estimated 261 have 1,500 or fewer
employees and 152 have more than
1,500 employees. Therefore, a little less
than one third of these entities can be
considered small.
60. Cable and Other Subscription
Programming. This industry comprises
establishments primarily engaged in
operating studios and facilities for the
broadcasting of programs on a
subscription or fee basis. The broadcast
programming is typically narrowcast in
nature (e.g., limited format, such as
news, sports, education, or youthoriented). These establishments produce
programming in their own facilities or
acquire programming from external
sources. The programming material is
usually delivered to a third party, such
as cable systems or direct-to-home
satellite systems, for transmission to
viewers. The SBA has established a size
standard for this industry stating that a
business in this industry is small if it
has 1,500 or fewer employees. The 2012
Economic Census indicates that 367
firms were operational for that entire
year. Of this total, 357 operated with
less than 1,000 employees. Accordingly
we conclude that a substantial majority
of firms in this industry are small under
the applicable SBA size standard.
61. Cable Companies and Systems
(Rate Regulation). The Commission has
developed its own small business size
standards for the purpose of cable rate
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:09 Jun 28, 2018
Jkt 244001
regulation. Under the Commission’s
rules, a ‘‘small cable company’’ is one
serving 400,000 or fewer subscribers
nationwide. Industry data indicate that
there are currently 4,600 active cable
systems in the United States. Of this
total, all but eleven cable operators
nationwide are small under the 400,000subscriber size standard. In addition,
under the Commission’s rate regulation
rules, a ‘‘small system’’ is a cable system
serving 15,000 or fewer subscribers.
Current Commission records show 4,600
cable systems nationwide. Of this total,
3,900 cable systems have fewer than
15,000 subscribers, and 700 systems
have 15,000 or more subscribers, based
on the same records. Thus, under this
standard as well, we estimate that most
cable systems are small entities.
62. Cable System Operators (Telecom
Act Standard). The Communications
Act also contains a size standard for
small cable system operators, which is
‘‘a cable operator that, directly or
through an affiliate, serves in the
aggregate fewer than 1 percent of all
subscribers in the United States and is
not affiliated with any entity or entities
whose gross annual revenues in the
aggregate exceed $250,000,000.’’ There
are approximately 52,403,705 cable
video subscribers in the United States
today. Accordingly, an operator serving
fewer than 524,037 subscribers shall be
deemed a small operator if its annual
revenues, when combined with the total
annual revenues of all its affiliates, do
not exceed $250 million in the
aggregate. Based on available data, we
find that all but nine incumbent cable
operators are small entities under this
size standard. We note that the
Commission neither requests nor
collects information on whether cable
system operators are affiliated with
entities whose gross annual revenues
exceed $250 million. Although it seems
certain that some of these cable system
operators are affiliated with entities
whose gross annual revenues exceed
$250 million, we are unable at this time
to estimate with greater precision the
number of cable system operators that
would qualify as small cable operators
under the definition in the
Communications Act.
63. All Other Telecommunications.
The ‘‘All Other Telecommunications’’
industry is comprised of establishments
that are primarily engaged in providing
specialized telecommunications
services, such as satellite tracking,
communications telemetry, and radar
station operation. This industry also
includes establishments primarily
engaged in providing satellite terminal
stations and associated facilities
connected with one or more terrestrial
PO 00000
Frm 00049
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
30637
systems and capable of transmitting
telecommunications to, and receiving
telecommunications from, satellite
systems. Establishments providing
internet services or voice over internet
protocol (VoIP) services via clientsupplied telecommunications
connections are also included in this
industry. The SBA has developed a
small business size standard for ‘‘All
Other Telecommunications,’’ which
consists of all such firms with gross
annual receipts of $32.5 million or less.
For this category, U.S. Census data for
2012 show that there were 1,442 firms
that operated for the entire year. Of
these firms, a total of 1,400 had gross
annual receipts of less than $25 million.
Thus a majority of ‘‘All Other
Telecommunications’’ firms potentially
may be affected by our action can be
considered small.
D. Description of Projected Reporting,
Recordkeeping, and Other Compliance
Requirements for Small Entities
64. The NPRM proposes and seeks
comment on rule changes that will
affect LECs and intermediate access
providers, including CEA providers.
The NPRM proposes rules to further
limit or eliminate the occurrence of
access arbitrage, including access
stimulation, which could reduce
potential reporting requirements. One
possible result of the proposed rules
would be greater availability of direct
connections between IXCs and accessstimulating LECs to avoid the use of
intervening third parties, including CEA
providers, and thus create more efficient
and economical network connections.
Direct connections would also likely
reduce recordkeeping requirements.
Specifically, we propose amending our
rules to allow access-stimulating LECs
to choose either to be financially
responsible for the delivery of calls to
their networks or to accept direct
connections from IXCs or from
intermediate access providers of the
IXC’s choosing. The proposed rules also
contain notification requirements for
access-stimulating LECs, which may
impact small entities. Some of these
requirements may also involve tariff
changes.
65. The NPRM also seeks comment on
other actions the Commission could
take to further discourage or eliminate
access arbitrage activity. Rules which
achieve these objectives could
potentially affect recordkeeping and
reporting requirements.
E:\FR\FM\29JNP1.SGM
29JNP1
sradovich on DSK3GMQ082PROD with PROPOSALS
30638
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 126 / Friday, June 29, 2018 / Proposed Rules
E. Steps Taken To Minimize the
Significant Economic Impact on Small
Entities, and Significant Alternatives
Considered
66. The RFA requires an agency to
describe any significant, specifically
small business, alternatives that it has
considered in reaching its proposed
approach, which may include the
following four alternatives (among
others): (1) The establishment of
differing compliance or reporting
requirements or timetables that take into
account the resources available to small
entities; (2) the clarification,
consolidation, or simplification of
compliance and reporting requirements
under the rules for such small entities;
(3) the use of performance rather than
design standards; and (4) an exemption
from coverage of the rule, or any part
thereof, for such small entities.
67. This NPRM invites comment on a
number of proposals and alternatives to
modify or adopt access arbitrage rules
and on the legality of access stimulation
generally. The Commission has found
these arbitrage practices inefficient and
to ultimately increase consumer
telecommunications rates. The NPRM
proposes rules to further limit or
eliminate the occurrence of access
stimulation as well as other access
arbitrage in turn promoting the efficient
function of the nation’s
telecommunications network. We
believe that if companies are able to
operate with greater efficiency this will
benefit the communications network as
a whole, and its users, by allowing
companies to increase their investment
in broadband deployment. Thus, we
propose to adopt rules to give accessstimulating LECs two choices about how
they connect to IXCs. First, an accessstimulating LEC can choose to be
financially responsible for calls
delivered to its networks so it, rather
than IXCs, pays for the delivery of calls
to its end office or the functional
equivalent. Or, second, instead of
accepting this financial responsibility,
an access-stimulating LEC can choose to
accept direct connections from either
the IXC or an intermediate access
provider of the IXC’s choosing. In the
alternative, we seek comment on
moving all traffic bound for an accessstimulating LEC to bill-and-keep. The
NPRM also seeks comment on potential
revisions to the definition of access
stimulation, in particular to address
intermediate access providers. The
record in this proceeding suggests
additional access arbitrage activities are
occurring, including: (1) Use of
intermediate access providers by
Commercial Mobile Radio Carriers; (2)
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:09 Jun 28, 2018
Jkt 244001
mileage pumping; and (3) daisy
chaining. Comment is sought on how
best to address these activities. The
NPRM seeks comment on the costs and
benefits of these proposals. Providing
carriers, especially small carriers, with
options will enable them to best assess
the financial effects on their operation
allowing them to determine how best to
respond.
68. The NPRM also seeks comment on
other actions we can take to further
discourage or eliminate access arbitrage
activity. Comment is sought on
alternatives to our proposal that could
be considered to achieve our objectives
with potentially less impact on small
entities.
F. Federal Rules That May Duplicate,
Overlap, or Conflict With the Proposed
Rules
69. None.
VI. Ordering Clauses
70. Accordingly, it is ordered that,
pursuant to sections 1, 2, 4(i), 201–206,
214, 218–220, 251, 252, 254, 256, 303(r),
and 403 of the Communications Act of
1934, as amended, and section 706 of
the Telecommunications Act of 1996, 47
U.S.C. 151, 152, 154(i), 201–206, 218–
220, 251, 252, 254, 256, 303(r), and 403,
and § 1.1 of the Commission’s rules, 47
CFR 1.1, this Notice of Proposed
Rulemaking is adopted.
71. It is further ordered that pursuant
to applicable procedures set forth in
§§ 1.415 and 1.419 of the Commission’s
rules, 47 CFR 1.415, 1.419, interested
parties may file comments on this
Notice of Proposed Rulemaking on or
before July 20, 2018 and reply
comments on or before August 3, 2018.
72. It is further ordered that the
Commission’s Consumer and
Governmental Affairs Bureau, Reference
Information Center, shall send a copy of
the Notice of Proposed Rulemaking,
including the Initial Regulatory
Flexibility Analysis, to the Chief
Counsel for Advocacy of the Small
Business Administration.
List of Subjects in 47 CFR Part 51
Common carriers, Communications.
Federal Communications Commission.
Marlene Dortch,
Secretary, Office of the Secretary.
Proposed Rules
For the reasons discussed in the
preamble, the Federal Communications
Commission proposes to amend 47 CFR
part 51 as follows:
PO 00000
Frm 00050
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
PART 51—INTERCONNECTION
1. The authority citation for part 51
continues to read as follows:
■
Authority: 47 U.S.C. 151–55, 201–05, 207–
09, 218, 220, 225–27, 251–54, 256, 271,
303(r), 332, 1302.
2. Amend § 51.903 by adding
paragraphs (k), (l), and (m) to read as
follows:
■
§ 51.903
Definitions.
*
*
*
*
*
(k) Access Stimulation has the same
meaning as that term is defined in
§ 61.3(bbb) of this chapter.
(l) Intermediate Access Provider
means any entity that carries or
processes traffic at any point between
the final Interexchange Carrier in a call
path and the carrier providing End
Office Access Service.
(m) Interexchange Carrier means a
telecommunications carrier that uses the
exchange access or information access
services of another telecommunications
carrier for the provision of
telecommunications.
■ 3. Add § 51.914 to read as follows:
§ 51.914 Additional provisions applicable
to Access Stimulation traffic.
(a) Notwithstanding any other
provision of the Commission’s rules, if
a local exchange carrier is engaged in
Access Stimulation, it shall within 45
days of commencing Access
Stimulation, or by [date 45 days after
the effective date of the final rule],
whichever is later:
(1)(i) Not bill any affected
Interexchange Carrier or any
Intermediate Access Provider for the
terminating switched access tandem
switching or any terminating switched
access transport charges for any traffic
between such local exchange carrier’s
terminating end office or equivalent and
the associated access tandem switch;
and
(ii) Assume financial responsibility
for the applicable Intermediate Access
Provider terminating tandem switching
and terminating switched transport
access charges relating to traffic bound
for the access-stimulating local
exchange carrier; or
(2) Upon request of an Interexchange
Carrier for direct-trunked transport
service, provision and enable directtrunked transport service to either the
Interexchange Carrier or an Intermediate
Access Provider of the Interexchange
Carrier’s choosing within [period of
time to be determined] of such a
request.
(b) Notwithstanding any other
provision of the Commission’s rules, if
a local exchange carrier is engaged in
E:\FR\FM\29JNP1.SGM
29JNP1
sradovich on DSK3GMQ082PROD with PROPOSALS
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 126 / Friday, June 29, 2018 / Proposed Rules
Access Stimulation, it shall within 45
days of commencing Access
Stimulation, or by [date 45 days after
effective date of the final rule],
whichever is later, notify in writing all
Intermediate Access Providers which it
subtends and Interexchange Carriers
with which it does business of the
following:
(1) That it is a local exchange carrier
engaged in Access Stimulation;
(2) That it will either:
(i) Obtain and pay for terminating
access services from Intermediate
Access Providers for such traffic as of
that date; or
(ii) Offer direct-trunked transport
service to any affected Interexchange
Carrier (or to an Intermediate Access
Provider of the Interexchange Carrier’s
choosing); and
(3) To the extent that the local
exchange carrier engaged in Access
Stimulation intends to comply with
paragraph (a) of this section through
electing the option described in
paragraph (a)(2) of this section,
designate where on its network it will
accept the requested direct connection.
(c) Nothing in this section creates an
independent obligation for a local
exchange carrier to construct new
facilities other than, as necessary,
adding switch trunk ports.
(d) In the event that an Intermediate
Access Provider receives notice under
paragraph (b) of this section that a local
exchange carrier engaged in Access
Stimulation will be obtaining and
paying for terminating access service
from such Intermediate Access Provider,
an Intermediate Access Provider shall
not bill Interexchange Carriers
terminating tandem switching and
terminating switched transport access
for traffic bound for such local exchange
carrier but, instead bill such local
exchange carrier for such services.
(e) Notwithstanding any provision of
this section, any carrier that is not itself
engaged in Access Stimulation, as that
term is defined in § 61.3(bbb) of this
chapter, but serves as an Intermediate
Access Provider with respect to traffic
bound for an access-stimulating local
exchange carrier, shall not itself be
deemed a local exchange carrier
engaged in Access Stimulation or be
affected by this rule other than
paragraph (d) of this section.
■ 4. Amend § 51.917 by revising
paragraph (c) to read as follows:
§ 51.917 Revenue recovery for Rate-ofReturn Carriers.
*
*
*
*
*
(c) Adjustment for Access Stimulation
activity. 2011 Rate-of-Return Carrier
Base Period Revenue shall be adjusted
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:09 Jun 28, 2018
Jkt 244001
to reflect the removal of any increases
in revenue requirement or revenues
resulting from Access Stimulation
activity the Rate-of-Return Carrier
engaged in during the relevant
measuring period. A Rate-of-Return
Carrier should make this adjustment for
its initial July 1, 2012, tariff filing, but
the adjustment may result from a
subsequent Commission or court ruling.
*
*
*
*
*
[FR Doc. 2018–13699 Filed 6–28–18; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6712–01–P
FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS
COMMISSION
47 CFR Part 76
[MB Docket Nos. 07–42 and 17–105; FCC
18–80]
Leased Commercial Access;
Modernization of Media Regulation
Initiative
Federal Communications
Commission.
ACTION: Proposed rule.
AGENCY:
In this document, the
Commission seeks to update its leased
access rules as part of its Modernization
of Media Regulation Initiative. First, the
Commission tentatively concludes that
it should vacate its 2008 Leased Access
Order, which the U.S. Court of Appeals
for the Sixth Circuit has stayed for a
decade in conjunction with several
judicial appeals of the order. Second,
the Commission seeks input on the state
of the leased access marketplace
generally and invites comment on ways
to modernize its existing leased access
rules.
DATES: Comments are due on or before
July 30, 2018; reply comments are due
on or before August 13, 2018.
ADDRESSES: You may submit comments,
identified by MB Docket Nos. 18–80 and
17–105, by any of the following
methods:
• Federal eRulemaking Portal: https://
www.regulations.gov. Follow the
instructions for submitting comments.
• Federal Communications
Commission’s website: https://
fjallfoss.fcc.gov/ecfs2/. Follow the
instructions for submitting comments.
• Mail: Filings can be sent by hand or
messenger delivery, by commercial
overnight courier, or by first-class or
overnight U.S. Postal Service mail. All
filings must be addressed to the
Commission’s Secretary, Office of the
Secretary, Federal Communications
Commission.
• People with Disabilities: Contact the
FCC to request reasonable
SUMMARY:
PO 00000
Frm 00051
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
30639
accommodations (accessible format
documents, sign language interpreters,
CART, etc.) by email: FCC504@fcc.gov
or phone: (202) 418–0530 or TTY: (202)
418–0432.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: For
additional information on this
proceeding, contact Diana Sokolow,
Diana.Sokolow@fcc.gov, of the Policy
Division, Media Bureau, (202) 418–
2120.
This is a
summary of the Commission’s Further
Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, FCC
18–80, adopted on June 7, 2018 and
released on June 8, 2017. The full text
is available for public inspection and
copying during regular business hours
in the FCC Reference Center, Federal
Communications Commission, 445 12th
Street SW, Room CY–A257,
Washington, DC 20554. This document
will also be available via ECFS at https://
fjallfoss.fcc.gov/ecfs/. Documents will
be available electronically in ASCII,
Microsoft Word, and/or Adobe Acrobat.
Alternative formats are available for
people with disabilities (Braille, large
print, electronic files, audio format), by
sending an email to fcc504@fcc.gov or
calling the Commission’s Consumer and
Governmental Affairs Bureau at (202)
418–0530 (voice), (202) 418–0432
(TTY).
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION:
Synopsis
1. In this Further Notice of Proposed
Rulemaking (FNPRM), we seek to
update our leased access rules as part of
the Commission’s Modernization of
Media Regulation Initiative. In response
to the public notice initiating the media
modernization proceeding, some
commenters made proposals related to
the Commission’s leased access rules,
which require cable operators to set
aside channel capacity for commercial
use by unaffiliated video programmers.1
By addressing these proposals in this
FNPRM, we advance our efforts to
modernize our media regulations and
remove unnecessary requirements that
can impede competition and innovation
in the media marketplace.
2. We tentatively conclude that we
should vacate the 2008 Leased Access
Order, including the Further Notice of
Proposed Rulemaking issued in
conjunction with that order. This action
would enable the Commission to clean
up a longstanding backlog and position
us to freshly consider new revisions to
1 The leased access rules are in Subpart N of Part
76, which was listed in the Media Modernization
Public Notice as one of the principal rule parts that
pertains to media entities and that is the subject of
the media modernization review.
E:\FR\FM\29JNP1.SGM
29JNP1
Agencies
[Federal Register Volume 83, Number 126 (Friday, June 29, 2018)]
[Proposed Rules]
[Pages 30628-30639]
From the Federal Register Online via the Government Publishing Office [www.gpo.gov]
[FR Doc No: 2018-13699]
=======================================================================
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION
47 CFR Part 51
[WC Docket No. 18-155; FCC 18-68]
Updating the Intercarrier Compensation Regime To Eliminate Access
Arbitrage
AGENCY: Federal Communications Commission.
ACTION: Proposed rule.
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
SUMMARY: In this document, the Commission proposed to adopt rules to
curb the financial incentive to engage in access stimulation by giving
access-stimulating LECs two choices for receiving calls. The access-
stimulating LEC can choose either: To be financially responsible for
the delivery of calls to its network, in which case intermediate access
providers would charge the access-stimulating LEC for the delivery of
calls; or to accept direct connections from long distance carriers
seeking to terminate telephone calls to the LEC or from intermediate
access providers of the long distance carriers' choosing, which would
allow the long distance carriers to bypass intermediate access
providers chosen by the access-stimulating LEC. This document seeks
comment on several alternatives, including requiring LECs engaged in
access stimulation to immediately transition their terminating access
[[Page 30629]]
charges to bill-and-keep. This document also seeks comment on the
effect the proposed rules will have on specific arbitrage schemes
described in the record. Finally, it seeks comment on how to curb other
arbitrage schemes.
DATES: Comments are due on or before July 20, 2018; reply comments are
due on or before August 3, 2018.
ADDRESSES: You may submit comments, identified by WC Docket No. 18-155,
by any of the following methods:
Federal Communications Commission's website: https://apps.fcc.gov/ecfs//. Follow the instructions for submitting comments.
People with Disabilities: Contact the FCC to request
reasonable accommodations (accessible format documents, sign language
interpreters, CART, etc.) by email: [email protected] or phone: 202-418-
0530 or TTY: 888-835-5322.
For detailed instructions for submitting comments and additional
information on the rulemaking process, see the SUPPLEMENTARY
INFORMATION section of this document.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: Edward Krachmer, FCC Wireline
Competition Bureau, Pricing Policy Division at 202-418-1525, or at
[email protected].
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: This is a summary of the Commission's Notice
of Proposed Rulemaking (NPRM), WC Docket No. 18-155; FCC 18-68, adopted
on June 4, 2018 and released on June 5, 2018. The full text of this
document may be obtained at the following internet address: https://www.fcc.gov/document/fcc-proposes-reforms-eliminate-intercarrier-compensation-arbitrage.
I. Background
A. The Current Access Stimulation Rules
1. To reduce access stimulation, as part of the USF/ICC
Transformation Order, 76 FR 73860, FCC 11-161, the Commission defined
``access stimulation'' as occurring when two conditions are met. First,
the involved LEC must have a ``revenue sharing agreement,'' which may
be ``express, implied, written or oral'' that ``over the course of the
agreement, would directly or indirectly result in a net payment to the
other party (including affiliates) to the agreement, in which payment''
by the LEC is ``based on the billing or collection of access charges
from interexchange carriers or wireless carriers.'' Second, the LEC
must also meet one of two traffic tests. An access-stimulating LEC
either has ``an interstate terminating-to-originating traffic ratio of
at least 3:1 in a calendar month, has had more than a 100 percent
growth in interstate originating and/or terminating switched access
minutes of use in a month compared to the same month in the preceding
year.'' Even if a LEC no longer meets either of these traffic tests,
once it is considered to have engaged in access stimulation, this
regulatory classification persists so long as the LEC maintains any
revenue sharing agreement.
2. A LEC that is engaged in access stimulation is required by our
rules to reduce its access charges either by adjusting its rates to
account for its high traffic volumes (if a rate-of-return LEC) or to
reduce its access charges to those of the price cap LEC with the lowest
switched access rates in the state (if a competitive LEC). These
reduced rates lower the cost to interexchange carriers (IXCs) and the
amount received by the LEC and the provider of high call volume
services with which it has a revenue sharing agreement.
B. Arbitrage Schemes After the USF/ICC Transformation Order
3. Last year, the Wireline Competition Bureau (Bureau) issued a
public notification, 82 FR 44754, seeking to refresh the record on ICC
issues raised by the Commission in the USF/ICC Transformation Order. In
response to that public notification, commenters argue that,
notwithstanding prior Commission action, arbitrage continues as
``companies engaged in access stimulation use a variety of tactics to
prevent interexchange carriers from avoiding their excessive charges.''
The record indicates that today's access arbitrage schemes are often
enabled by the use of intermediate access providers selected by the
terminating LECs. When an intermediate access provider is in the call
path, the IXC pays access charges on a per-minute-of-use (MOU) basis to
the intermediate access provider and to the terminating LEC. This
tactic evades existing Commission rules intended to stop access
stimulation to the extent that an intermediate access provider is not
captured by the definition of ``access stimulation,'' and thus, is not
subject to those rules.
4. Recent complaint activity suggests that much of the post-USF/ICC
Transformation Order access arbitrage activity specifically involves
LECs that use centralized equal access (CEA) providers to connect to
IXCs. CEA providers are a specialized type of intermediate access
provider that were formed in the 1980s to implement long distance equal
access obligations (permitting end users to use 1+ dialing to reach the
IXC of their choice) and to aggregate traffic for connection between
rural incumbent LECs and other networks, particularly those of IXCs.
There are currently three CEA providers, and the LECs that use them
(subtending LECs) have traditionally been reliant on CEA providers for
this equal access implementation as well as traffic measurement and
billing.
II. Discussion
5. We propose solutions to the persistent, costly, and inefficient
access stimulation arbitrage scheme described here and seek comment on
how to prevent other types of arbitrage. We are mindful of the fact
that practices adjust to regulatory change; therefore we invite comment
on how to avoid introducing incentives for new types of arbitrage to
arise.
A. Requiring Access-Stimulating LECs Either To Be Financially
Responsible for Calls Delivered to Their Networks or To Accept Direct
Connections
6. To rid the ICC system of the inefficiencies caused by access
stimulation relating to intermediate access providers, we propose to
require access-stimulating LECs to choose either to: (i) Bear the
financial responsibility for the delivery of terminating traffic to
their end office, or functional equivalent, or; (ii) accept direct
connections from either the IXC or an intermediate access provider of
the IXC's choice.
7. Revised Financial Responsibility. We seek comment on the first
prong of our proposal and the impact it will have on access stimulation
schemes. Under this prong, an access-stimulating LEC that does not
offer direct connections to IXCs would bear all financial
responsibility for applicable intermediate access provider terminating
charges normally assessed to an IXC (from the point of indirect
interconnection to the access-stimulating LEC's end office or
functional equivalent), and would be prohibited from assessing
transport charges for any portion of transport between the intermediate
access provider and the LEC's end office or functional equivalent that
the LEC, itself, provides. What are the advantages of placing the
financial responsibility for delivery of traffic to its end office, or
functional equivalent, on the access-stimulating LEC? Are there
disadvantages?
8. What implementation issues does this part of our proposal raise?
What steps would intermediate access providers need to take to bill
access-stimulating LECs for terminating access
[[Page 30630]]
and to not bill IXCs? How much time do access-stimulating LECs and
intermediate access providers need to make modifications necessary to
accomplish this proposed change in financial responsibility? We propose
to require carriers to come into compliance with these requirements
within 45 days of the effective date of any revised rule. Is that
timeframe sufficient? For example, is it possible to implement
necessary billing system changes within that time frame? We similarly
propose to require any carriers that newly qualify as access-
stimulating LECs to come into compliance with these requirements within
45 days of such qualification.
9. For purposes of this proposal, we propose to define
``intermediate access provider'' as ``any entity that carries or
processes traffic at any point between the final interexchange carrier
in a call path and the carrier providing end office access service.''
We seek comment on the use of this definition in this context. Does it
adequately capture the types of intermediate access providers currently
benefiting from access stimulation schemes? Is it too narrow or too
broad?
10. Direct Connection. Commenters have argued that the volume of
traffic bound for access-stimulating LECs justifies direct connections,
but allege that access-stimulating LECs currently refuse to accept such
connections. Direct connections do not pass through intermediate
switches and are offered on a capacity basis at monthly-recurring
rates, as opposed to a per-MOU rate. If there is a sufficient volume of
traffic, the monthly charges for direct connections can often be
substantially lower than per-MOU rates for an equivalent amount of
traffic. As the second prong of our proposal, we propose to provide
access-stimulating LECs the option to offer to connect directly to the
IXC or an intermediate access provider of the IXC's choice as an
alternative to bearing financial responsibility for intermediate access
provider charges and ceasing to bill their own transport charges. Under
this proposal, IXCs would have the option of selecting an intermediate
access provider that would bill the IXC for transport to the access-
stimulating LEC on a dedicated basis. We seek comment on this proposal
and on how best to implement it. We note that as a result of this
election, an IXC would have the choice to connect with an access-
stimulating LEC directly or indirectly through the LEC's existing
intermediate access provider or another IXC directly connecting to the
access-stimulating LEC.
[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP29JN18.009
11. For direct connections between an IXC (or an intermediate
access provider of the IXC's choosing) and an access-stimulating LEC to
be established, not only must the access-stimulating LEC be willing and
able to accept direct connections, but arrangements need to be made
between the IXCs seeking to avail themselves of such connections and
the LEC. If we adopt the approach we propose today, how long should we
give existing access-stimulating LECs to indicate their willingness to
accept direct connections and how long should we give them to implement
those direct connections? How detailed a timeline should we adopt for
this process? Should we adopt rules regarding the
[[Page 30631]]
conduct of any negotiations for direct connections? For example, should
we adopt a timeframe within which negotiations must be concluded before
the LEC must assume financial responsibility for the delivery of
traffic or the impasse submitted to arbitration? Similarly, if, at some
later date, an access-stimulating LEC decides to offer direct
connections, what process should the access-stimulating LEC need to
follow to cease bearing the financial obligation for the intermediate
access providers' charges? How should we address LECs that meet the
definition of access-stimulating LEC after adoption of our rules? If
they chose to offer direct connections, what time frame should we
provide for making and implementing that decision?
12. We propose to adopt a rule that makes clear that allowing
access-stimulating LECs to accept direct connection as a means of not
bearing financial responsibility for intermediate access provider
charges does not carry with it an obligation for such LECs to extend
their networks absent a request and an independent obligation to do so.
Is this a reasonable limitation? Are there any other limitations or
exceptions we should apply? Are there other rules we should adopt to
help providers implement the option to accept direct connections if a
provider makes that choice? For example, because IXCs are not currently
directly connected to access-stimulating LECs in the scenario to which
our proposal applies, a third-party vendor may need to connect the two
networks via dedicated transport such as, perhaps, the current
intermediate access provider. Are there any rules that we should adopt
to facilitate such arrangements?
13. One result of permitting access-stimulating LECs that subtend
CEA providers to connect with IXCs directly (or an intermediate access
provider of an IXC's choice) would be to end the ``mandatory use''
policy applicable to some CEA providers, at least with respect to
access-stimulating LECs. Historically, this mandatory use policy has
permitted the CEA providers in Iowa and South Dakota to require IXCs to
connect to LECs that subtend the CEA provider indirectly through the
CEA provider's tandem switch rather than indirectly through another
intermediate access provider or directly to the subtending LEC. In
initially permitting this practice almost thirty years ago, the
Commission concluded that it ``[did] not believe that the mandatory
termination requirement for interstate traffic is unreasonable or
differs substantially from the normal way access is provided, as both
an originating and terminating service by the local exchange company.''
14. It appears that access stimulation, particularly when practiced
by competitive LECs, which were formed well after CEA providers were
established, presents a reasonable circumstance for departing from the
policy of permitting mandatory use requirements because delivery of
such traffic, particularly in the pertinent volumes, was not the
purpose for which CEA providers were formed. We seek comment on this
assumption, and on the impact of this proposal on CEA providers, on the
LECs that subtend CEA providers, and on the customers of such
subtending LECs. For example, to the extent that creating the
opportunity for access-stimulation traffic to bypass CEA providers
threatens the viability of CEA providers, we seek comment on whether
and how this potential effect should be addressed. Are there other
companies that can perform the traditional functions of CEA providers,
including equal access implementation and traffic measurement and
billing? Recognizing that most states do not have CEA providers, are
there ways that equal access and traffic identification and measurement
are handled by small LECs in those states that can inform our decision
making in this proceeding?
15. Notice Requirement. We propose to require access-stimulating
LECs to notify affected IXCs and intermediate access providers of their
intent to accept financial responsibility for calls delivered to their
networks or to accept direct connections from IXCs or intermediate
access providers of the IXCs' choosing. Should we also require the
access-stimulating LEC to provide public, written notice of its choice
to the Commission? Should we provide specific requirements regarding
the form and content of such notice? For example, should we require an
access-stimulating LEC to accept direct connections at current points
of interconnection (POI) with intermediate access providers, as well as
at the LECs' end office, and to provide notice of those locations? Or,
should we allow an access-stimulating LEC to choose where to provide
POIs and to specify those locations in its notice? Should access-
stimulating LECs also provide notice to the Commission and state
commissions of their choice to accept direct connections and of the
location of their POIs? To ensure that the investment made by an IXC to
extend its network to directly interconnect with an access-stimulating
LEC is not stranded, should an access-stimulating LEC be prohibited
from ending its election of direct connections once made? Should such a
prohibition be permanent or for a specified period of time?
16. Impact of this Proposal. We seek comment on the costs and
benefits of our proposal. To what extent will our two-pronged proposal
alleviate market distortions created by the ability of access-
stimulating LECs to bill for switched transport services at rates that
our rules have not required to be reduced below 2011 interstate levels?
Will the incentives created by our proposal for access-stimulating LECs
to accept direct connections (to avoid bearing intermediate access
provider charges imposed by a provider of the access-stimulating LEC's
choosing) alleviate the problem of IXCs paying relatively-high tandem-
switched transport rates by giving IXCs more options to reach end
users?
17. How will our proposal affect incentives for carriers to migrate
their services to IP? To what extent do parties expect that direct
connections would be provided in time division multiplexed (TDM) format
rather than IP? Are there circumstances under which an access-
stimulating LEC should be required, upon request, to interconnect using
IP rather than TDM and bear any costs necessary to do so? Are calls
bound for high call volume service providers ultimately converted to IP
for delivery? Would requiring IP interconnection obviate the need to
convert TDM traffic to IP for delivery?
18. NTCA et al. Proposal. NTCA et al. has recommended that we adopt
rules similar to the first prong of our proposal, but without providing
an access-stimulating LEC the option of electing to accept direct
connections as a means of avoiding bearing intermediate access provider
charges. Under the NTCA et al. proposal, within 45 days of the
effective date of the implementing rules, access-stimulating LECs would
be required to revise their tariffs to remove any terminating
interstate tandem switching and tandem transport charges of their own
and also begin to assume financial responsibility for all intermediate
switched access provider interstate tandem switching and transport
charges for traffic bound for such access-stimulating LECs. The NTCA et
al. proposal would also require access-stimulating LECs to provide
written notice to all affected providers, including intermediate access
providers, of the substance of these tariff revisions at the time that
such tariff revisions are filed, as well as the fact that such access-
stimulating LECs will be bearing financial responsibility for pertinent
intermediate switched access provider interstate tandem switching and
transport charges.
[[Page 30632]]
19. Although the NTCA et al. proposal does not preclude an access-
stimulating LEC from avoiding incurring intermediate access provider
charges by beginning to accept direct connections, it also does not
provide IXCs any incentive to accept offers of direct connection from
such LECs. By permitting access-stimulating LECs to elect to accept
direct connections, our proposal seeks to provide a formal means by
which access-stimulating LECs may eventually avoid incurring
intermediate access provider charges. We seek comment on the NTCA et
al. proposal both as an independent proposal and also as it relates to
our proposal above.
20. CenturyLink Proposal. CenturyLink suggests that we consider an
approach similar to our proposal, but with broader applicability.
Rather than focusing on access-stimulating LECs, CenturyLink recommends
shifting financial responsibility to any LEC that declines to accept a
request for direct interconnection for the purpose of terminating
access traffic. We seek comment on this recommendation. What would be
the impact of such an approach on the affected companies and their
customers?
B. Requiring All Access-Stimulating LECs To Transition to Bill-and-Keep
21. If we do not adopt rules requiring access-stimulating LECs to
either choose to accept financial responsibility for the delivery of
calls or to accept direct connections, should we reduce all terminating
tandem switching, common transport, and tandem-switched transport rate
elements for access stimulators to bill-and-keep? Moving these access
charges to bill-and-keep would be consistent with our overarching goals
of discouraging arbitrage, in particular access stimulation, and
ultimately transitioning all traffic to bill-and-keep. It would also be
consistent with the Commission's finding in the USF/ICC Transformation
Order that with respect to terminating traffic, the LEC's end user is
the cost causer and therefore the LEC should look first to its
subscribers to recover the costs of it network. To what extent would
this approach resolve the access arbitrage concerns identified in this
NPRM? We also seek comment on how this approach fits with the other
proposals in this NPRM. For example, if we reduce all terminating
access charges to bill-and-keep is there any remaining incentive for
carriers to stimulate traffic? We also seek comment on any
implementation issues or concerns related to the proposal. Should we
provide for a transition period to bill-and-keep for access
stimulators? If so, how long should the transition last and what steps
should it include?
22. We also seek comment on whether to require an access-
stimulating LEC to transition its dedicated transport and originating
rates to bill-and-keep. The only potential access arbitrage scheme of
which we are aware regarding originating access concerns 8YY traffic,
which we leave for separate consideration. Outside the 8YY context, are
there arbitrage schemes involving originating access about which we
should be concerned? Can they be addressed by a transition to bill-and-
keep or by other proposals in this NPRM?
C. Defining Access Stimulation
23. Given evidence that access stimulation schemes are still being
perpetrated notwithstanding our existing rules, we seek comment on
whether, and if so how, to revise the current definition of access
stimulation to more accurately and effectively target harmful access
stimulation practices. What has been the impact of the current
definition over the last seven years? Has it proved effective at
identifying actors that are distorting the ICC system for their own
gain? If not, how can we revise the definition to more accurately
identify these types of harmful practices? Should we, for example,
modify the ratios or triggers in the definition? If so, how should
those ratios or triggers be modified? Should we adopt triggers that
relate to the stimulation of tandem and transport services? If so, what
should those triggers be? Is the current revenue sharing agreement
requirement in our rules sufficiently broad or should it be revised,
and if so how? Or, should we remove the revenue sharing portion of the
definition, because access stimulation seems to be occurring in some
instances even in the absence of revenue sharing? Do commenters believe
that revenue sharing alone is an indication of access stimulation? If
so, should we revise our rules so that the existence of a revenue
sharing agreement triggers the access stimulation rule? How will we
know if parties are engaged in revenue sharing? Should we require these
parties to self-report? If so, we seek comment on how to implement a
self-reporting requirement.
24. Alternatively, based on parties' experience with our existing
access stimulation rules, is there reason to find that access
stimulation itself is unjust and unreasonable because of the imposition
of excess charges on IXCs, wireless carriers, and their customers? Or,
is there a subset of such activities that we should separately identify
as unlawful?
25. To address specific concerns identified in the record,
commenters should also consider the extent to which the access
stimulation definition should be revised to address intermediate access
providers. Do intermediate access providers that are not engaged in
access stimulation as defined in our current rules nevertheless benefit
from access stimulation schemes? To remove incentives for intermediate
access providers to enable access arbitrage schemes, aside from the
proposals discussed above, should we adopt new access stimulation
rules, or modify our existing rules, to apply specifically to
intermediate access providers? Would doing so be unduly burdensome to
intermediate access providers or small LECs who subtend them? Are there
technical obstacles that would make it infeasible for intermediate
access providers to comply with the Commission's current, or any
modified, access stimulation rules? Would a requirement that access-
stimulating subtending LECs notify the intermediate access provider
that they are engaged in access stimulation and identify the traffic
that is being stimulated provide a practical solution?
D. Addressing Other Arbitrage Schemes, and Alternative Approaches to
Arbitrage
26. The record indicates the existence of at least three other
types of arbitrage schemes. We seek comment on the prevalence and
impact of these types of schemes described in more detail below. Will
any of the rules we propose today help retard these schemes? Are there
other rules we should adopt to prevent these schemes?
27. First, parties describe an access arbitrage scheme involving a
revenue sharing or other type of agreement between an intermediate
access provider and a terminating carrier that may not meet the
definition of access stimulation under our rules, such as a Commercial
Mobile Radio Service (CMRS) carrier. CMRS carriers are prohibited from
tariffing access charges. However, intermediate access providers that
transport traffic from an IXC to CMRS carriers can charge for access
services through filed tariffs or negotiated agreements. Some IXCs
claim that certain CMRS carriers that previously offered direct
connections between their networks and the IXCs' networks have begun to
use intermediate access providers to terminate their traffic from IXCs,
to reap the benefit of alleged revenue sharing
[[Page 30633]]
agreements with the intermediate access providers. Should we adopt
rules that discourage all revenue sharing agreements between
terminating providers and intermediate access providers? If a
terminating provider requires that some or all traffic be routed
through an intermediate access provider, should we require the
terminating provider to pay the intermediate access provider's charges?
Or are there instances where it is most efficient or beneficial in
other ways for a carrier to require traffic be routed through an
intermediate access provider? What would be the costs and benefits of
requiring a terminating provider that requires the use of a specific
intermediate access provider to pay the intermediate access provider's
charges? And would the cost-benefit analysis change if we focused any
such rules on large terminating providers--i.e., those with 100,000 or
more ``lines'' at the holding company level?
28. Second, because LECs and intermediate access providers receive
greater compensation from IXCs the further the LEC or intermediate
access provider carries the traffic to reach a POI with the IXC, some
commenters allege that LECs have changed their POI with IXCs for the
sole purpose of artificially inflating their per-MOU, per-mile
transport rates and revenue. This scheme is often referred to as
mileage pumping. Shortly after the USF/ICC Transformation Order, the
Commission released an order addressing this practice finding such
network changes were merely sham arrangements and that the LECs did not
have the unilateral right under their tariffs to make such changes.
Nevertheless, allegations of mileage pumping continue. We seek comment
on the prevalence of this practice, its impact in the market, and the
likely effect of the rules proposed in this NPRM on this concern. What
more can we do to prevent these practices?
29. Third, some commenters raise concerns about the addition of
superfluous network facilities for which the LEC can bill switched
access charges, but the rates for which are not subject to the current
transition to bill-and-keep. This practice is sometimes referred to as
``daisy chaining.'' This practice may inefficiently inflate per-mile
charges and insert unnecessary facilities to justify assessment of
additional rate elements, such as remote switches that subtend end
offices. What actions can we take to prevent daisy chaining?
30. Would the CenturyLink suggestion of shifting financial
responsibility to LECs that decline to accept direct connections
eliminate or reduce the three types of inefficient routing schemes
described above? Even if an IXC chose not to seek a direct connection,
would the risk of IXCs seeking direct connections provide a
disciplining counterweight to some providers' incentives to engage in
mileage pumping or daisy-chaining? What would be the impact on affected
parties?
E. Other Issues
31. We recognize that any action we take to address access
arbitrage may affect the costs to carriers and their customers and the
choices they make, as they provide and receive telecommunications
services. Consumers that enjoy high call volume services could be
affected by regulatory adjustments targeting arbitrage. Are there
efficiencies that are in the public's interest in what some describe as
arbitrage? Would addressing the arbitrage described here unfairly
advantage any particular competitor or class of competitors? If so, are
there alternative means to address the arbitrage issues described here
and presented in the record? How would the changes proposed herein
affect small businesses?
32. In the USF/ICC Transformation Order, the Commission considered
direct costs imposed on consumers by arbitrage schemes. The Commission
also found that access stimulation diverts ``capital away from more
productive uses such as broadband deployment.'' We believe this
continues to be true. Are there additional, more-current data available
to estimate the annual cost of arbitrage schemes to companies, long
distance rate payers, and consumers in general? Likewise, are there
data available to quantify the resources being diverted from
infrastructure investment because of arbitrage schemes? To what degree
are consumers indirectly affected by potentially inefficient networking
and cost recovery due to current regulations and the exploitation of
those regulations? Are there other costs or benefits we should
consider?
F. Legal Authority
33. The proposals in this NPRM, targeted to address the particular
issues described in the record, continue the work the Commission began
in the USF/ICC Transformation Order to stop economically wasteful
arbitrage activity and the damage it causes in telecommunications
markets. Therefore, we rely on the legal authority the Commission set
forth in the USF/ICC Transformation Order, as support for modifications
to rules we propose in this NPRM. The Commission made clear that its
rules to address access arbitrage would result in interstate access
rates ``consistent with section 201(b) of the Act.'' The Commission
likewise found that ``[o]ur statutory authority to implement bill-and-
keep as the default framework for the exchange of traffic with LECs
flows directly from sections 251(b)(5) and 201(b) of the Act.'' We seek
comment on whether additional statutory authority is available, or
necessary, to support the actions proposed here.
III. Rule Revisions
34. We seek comment on the rule changes proposed at the end of this
document. What, if any, other rule additions or modifications should we
make to codify these proposals? Are there any conforming rule changes
that commenters consider necessary? For example, we intend for any
rules that we adopt to apply not only to interstate traffic, but also
intrastate traffic. Do our proposed rules adequately address this? Are
there any conflicts or inconsistencies between existing rules and those
proposed herein? We ask commenters to provide any other proposed
actions and rule additions or modifications we should consider to
address the access arbitrage schemes described in this NPRM including
updates to any relevant comments or proposals made in response to the
USF/ICC Transformation FNPRM, 76 FR 78383.
IV. Procedural Matters
35. Filing Instructions. Pursuant to Sec. Sec. 1.415 and 1.419 of
the Commission's rules, 47 CFR 1.415, 1.419, interested parties may
file comments and reply comments on or before the dates indicated on
the first page of this document. Comments may be filed using the
Commission's Electronic Comment Filing System (ECFS). See Electronic
Filing of Documents in Rulemaking Proceedings, 63 FR 24121 (1998).
Electronic Filers: Comments may be filed electronically using
the internet by accessing the ECFS: https://www.fcc.gov/ecfs/
Paper Filers: Parties who choose to file by paper must file an
original and one copy of each filing. If more than one docket or
rulemaking number appears in the caption of this proceeding, filers
must submit two additional copies for each additional docket or
rulemaking number.
Filings can be sent by hand or messenger delivery, by commercial
overnight courier, or by first-class or overnight U.S. Postal Service
mail. All
[[Page 30634]]
filings must be addressed to the Commission's Secretary, Office of the
Secretary, Federal Communications Commission.
All hand-delivered or messenger-delivered paper filings
for the Commission's Secretary must be delivered to FCC Headquarters at
445 12th St. SW, Room TW-A325, Washington, DC 20554. The filing hours
are 8:00 a.m. to 7:00 p.m. All hand deliveries must be held together
with rubber bands or fasteners. Any envelopes and boxes must be
disposed of before entering the building.
Commercial overnight mail (other than U.S. Postal Service
Express Mail and Priority Mail) must be sent to 9050 Junction Drive,
Annapolis Junction, MD 20701.
U.S. Postal Service first-class, Express, and Priority
mail must be addressed to 445 12th Street SW, Washington, DC 20554.
36. People with Disabilities. To request materials in accessible
formats for people with disabilities (braille, large print, electronic
files, audio format), send an email to [email protected] or call the
Consumer & Governmental Affairs Bureau at 202-418-0530 (voice), 202-
418-0432 (tty).
37. Ex Parte Requirements. This proceeding shall be treated as a
``permit-but-disclose'' proceeding in accordance with the Commission's
ex parte rules. Persons making ex parte presentations must file a copy
of any written presentation or a memorandum summarizing any oral
presentation within two business days after the presentation (unless a
different deadline applicable to the Sunshine period applies). Persons
making oral ex parte presentations are reminded that memoranda
summarizing the presentation must: (1) List all persons attending or
otherwise participating in the meeting at which the ex parte
presentation was made; and (2) summarize all data presented and
arguments made during the presentation. If the presentation consisted
in whole or in part of the presentation of data or arguments already
reflected in the presenter's written comments, memoranda, or other
filings in the proceeding, the presenter may provide citations to such
data or arguments in his or her prior comments, memoranda, or other
filings (specifying the relevant page and/or paragraph numbers where
such data or arguments can be found) in lieu of summarizing them in the
memorandum. Documents shown or given to Commission staff during ex
parte meetings are deemed to be written ex parte presentations and must
be filed consistent with Rule 1.1206(b). In proceedings governed by
Rule 1.49(f) or for which the Commission has made available a method of
electronic filing, written ex parte presentations and memoranda
summarizing oral ex parte presentations, and all attachments thereto,
must be filed through the electronic comment filing system available
for that proceeding, and must be filed in their native format (e.g.,
.doc, .xml, .ppt, searchable .pdf). Participants in this proceeding
should familiarize themselves with the Commission's ex parte rules.
38. Paperwork Reduction Act Analysis. This document contains
proposed new and modified information collection requirements. The
Commission, as part of its continuing effort to reduce paperwork
burdens, invites the general public and the Office of Management and
Budget to comment on the information collection requirements contained
in this document, as required by the Paperwork Reduction Act of 1995,
Public Law 104-13. In addition, pursuant to the Small Business
Paperwork Relief Act of 2002, Public Law 107-198, see 44 U.S.C.
3506(c)(4), we seek specific comment on how we might further reduce the
information collection burden for small business concerns with fewer
than 25 employees.
39. Initial Regulatory Flexibility Act Analysis. Pursuant to the
Regulatory Flexibility Act (RFA), we have prepared an Initial
Regulatory Flexibility Analysis (IRFA) of the possible significant
economic impact on small entities of the policies and actions
considered in this NPRM. The Commission prepared an IRFA to accompany
the first Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking in this docket, USF/ICC
Transformation FNPRM. The questions asked in this NPRM are different
than those the Commission sought comment on previously. Therefore, we
have prepared a new IRFA to reflect the substance of this NPRM. The
text of the IRFA is set forth in section V of this document. Written
public comments are requested on this IRFA. Comments must be identified
as responses to the IRFA and must be filed by the deadlines for
comments on the NPRM. The Commission's Consumer and Governmental
Affairs Bureau, Reference Information Center, will send a copy of the
NPRM, including the IRFA, to the Chief Counsel for Advocacy of the
Small Business Administration.
40. Contact Person. For further information about this proceeding,
please contact Edward Krachmer, FCC Wireline Competition Bureau,
Pricing Policy Division, Room 5-A230, 445 12th Street SW, Washington,
DC 20554, (202) 418-1525, [email protected].
V. Initial Regulatory Flexibility Analysis
41. As required by the Regulatory Flexibility Act of 1980, as
amended (RFA), we have prepared this Initial Regulatory Flexibility
Analysis (IRFA) of the possible significant economic impact on a
substantial number of small entities by the policies and rules proposed
in this Notice of Proposed Rulemaking (NPRM). We request written public
comments on this IRFA. Comments must be identified as responses to the
IRFA and must be filed by the deadlines for comments provided on the
first page of the NPRM. We will send a copy of the NPRM, including this
IRFA, to the Chief Counsel for Advocacy of the Small Business
Administration (SBA). In addition, the NPRM and IRFA (or summaries
thereof) will be published in the Federal Register.
A. Need for, and Objective of, the Proposed Rules
42. In the USF/ICC Transformation FNPRM, the Commission sought
comment on additional steps to implement the bill-and-keep regime as
well as possible communications network definitional changes, the
appropriate recovery mechanisms going forward and VoIP and IP-to-IP
related intercarrier compensation issues. In this NPRM we propose to
adopt rules to address access arbitrage schemes that persist despite
previous Commission action. We propose to adopt rules to give access-
stimulating LECs two choices about how they connect to IXCs. First, an
access-stimulating LEC can choose to be financially responsible for
calls delivered to its networks so it, rather than IXCs, pays for the
delivery of calls to its end office or the functional equivalent. Or,
second, instead of accepting this financial responsibility, an access-
stimulating LEC can choose to accept direct connections from either the
IXC or an intermediate access provider of the IXC's choosing. In the
alternative, we seek comment on moving all traffic bound for an access-
stimulating LEC to bill-and-keep. The NPRM also seeks comment on
potential revisions to the definition of access stimulation, in
particular to address intermediate access providers. The record in this
proceeding suggests additional access arbitrage activities are
occurring, including: (1) Use of intermediate access providers by
Commercial Mobile Radio Carriers; (2) mileage pumping; and (3) daisy
chaining. Comment is sought on how best to address these activities.
The
[[Page 30635]]
NPRM seeks comment on the costs and benefits of these proposals.
B. Legal Basis
43. The legal basis for any action that may be taken pursuant to
this NPRM is contained in sections 1, 2, 4(i), 201-206, 214, 218-220,
251, 252, 254, 256, 303(r), and 403 of the Communications Act of 1934,
as amended, 47 U.S.C. 151, 152, 154(i), 201-206, 214, 218-220, 251,
252, 254, 256, 303(r), and 403.
C. Description and Estimate of the Number of Small Entities to Which
the Proposed Rules Will Apply
44. The RFA directs agencies to provide a description of, and where
feasible, an estimate of the number of small entities that may be
affected by the proposed rule revisions, if adopted. The RFA generally
defines the term ``small entity'' as having the same meaning as the
terms ``small business,'' ``small organization,'' and ``small
governmental jurisdiction.'' In addition, the term ``small business''
has the same meaning as the term ``small-business concern'' under the
Small Business Act. A ``small-business concern'' is one which: (1) Is
independently owned and operated; (2) is not dominant in its field of
operation; and (3) satisfies any additional criteria established by the
SBA.
45. Small Businesses, Small Organizations, Small Governmental
Jurisdictions. Our actions, over time, may affect small entities that
are not easily categorized at present. We therefore describe here, at
the outset, three comprehensive small entity size standards that could
be directly affected herein. First, while there are industry specific
size standards for small businesses that are used in the regulatory
flexibility analysis, according to data from the SBA's Office of
Advocacy, in general a small business is an independent business having
fewer than 500 employees. These types of small businesses represent
99.9% of all businesses in the United States which translates to 28.8
million businesses. Next, the type of small entity described as a
``small organization'' is generally ``any not-for-profit enterprise
which is independently owned and operated and is not dominant in its
field.'' Nationwide, as of August 2016, there were approximately
356,494 small organizations based on registration and tax data filed by
nonprofits with the Internal Revenue Service (IRS). Finally, the small
entity described as a ``small governmental jurisdiction'' is defined
generally as ``governments of cities, towns, townships, villages,
school districts, or special districts, with a population of less than
fifty thousand.'' U.S. Census Bureau data from the 2012 Census of
Governments indicate that there were 90,056 local governmental
jurisdictions consisting of general purpose governments and special
purpose governments in the United States. Of this number there were 37,
132 General purpose governments (county, municipal and town or
township) with populations of less than 50,000 and 12,184 Special
purpose governments (independent school districts and special
districts) with populations of less than 50,000. The 2012 U.S. Census
Bureau data for most types of governments in the local government
category show that the majority of these governments have populations
of less than 50,000. Based on this data we estimate that at least
49,316 local government jurisdictions fall in the category of ``small
governmental jurisdictions.''
46. Wired Telecommunications Carriers. The U.S. Census Bureau
defines this industry as ``establishments primarily engaged in
operating and/or providing access to transmission facilities and
infrastructure that they own and/or lease for the transmission of
voice, data, text, sound, and video using wired communications
networks. Transmission facilities may be based on a single technology
or a combination of technologies. Establishments in this industry use
the wired telecommunications network facilities that they operate to
provide a variety of services, such as wired telephony services,
including VoIP services, wired (cable) audio and video programming
distribution, and wired broadband internet services. By exception,
establishments providing satellite television distribution services
using facilities and infrastructure that they operate are included in
this industry.'' The SBA has developed a small business size standard
for Wired Telecommunications Carriers, which consists of all such
companies having 1,500 or fewer employees. Census data for 2012 show
that there were 3,117 firms that operated that year. Of this total,
3,083 operated with fewer than 1,000 employees. Thus, under this size
standard, the majority of firms in this industry can be considered
small.
47. Local Exchange Carriers (LECs). Neither the Commission nor the
SBA has developed a size standard for small businesses specifically
applicable to local exchange services. The closest applicable NAICS
Code category is Wired Telecommunications Carriers and under the
applicable SBA size standard, such a business is small if it has 1,500
or fewer employees. U.S. Census data for 2012 show that there were
3,117 firms that operated that year. Of that total, 3,083 operated with
fewer than 1,000 employees. Thus under this category and the associated
size standard, the Commission estimates that the majority of local
exchange carriers are small entities.
48. Incumbent LECs. Neither the Commission nor the SBA has
developed a small business size standard specifically for incumbent
local exchange services. The closest applicable NAICS Code category is
Wired Telecommunications Carriers as defined above. Under that size
standard, such a business is small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees.
According to Commission data, 3,117 firms operated in that year. Of
this total, 3,083 operated with fewer than 1,000 employees.
Consequently, the Commission estimates that most providers of incumbent
local exchange service are small businesses that may be affected by the
rules and policies adopted. Three hundred and seven (307) Incumbent
Local Exchange Carriers reported that they were incumbent local
exchange service providers. Of this total, an estimated 1,006 have
1,500 or fewer employees.
49. Competitive Local Exchange Carriers (Competitive LECs),
Competitive Access Providers (CAPs), Shared-Tenant Service Providers,
and Other Local Service Providers. Neither the Commission nor the SBA
has developed a small business size standard specifically for these
service providers. The appropriate NAICS Code category is Wired
Telecommunications Carriers, as defined above. Under that size
standard, such a business is small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees.
U.S. Census data for 2012 indicate that 3,117 firms operated during
that year. Of that number, 3,083 operated with fewer than 1,000
employees. Based on this data, the Commission concludes that the
majority of Competitive LECS, CAPs, Shared-Tenant Service Providers,
and Other Local Service Providers, are small entities. According to
Commission data, 1,442 carriers reported that they were engaged in the
provision of either competitive local exchange services or competitive
access provider services. Of these 1,442 carriers, an estimated 1,256
have 1,500 or fewer employees. In addition, 17 carriers have reported
that they are Shared-Tenant Service Providers, and all 17 are estimated
to have 1,500 or fewer employees. Also, 72 carriers have reported that
they are Other Local Service Providers. Of this total, 70 have 1,500 or
fewer employees. Consequently, based on internally researched FCC data,
the Commission
[[Page 30636]]
estimates that most providers of competitive local exchange service,
competitive access providers, Shared-Tenant Service Providers, and
Other Local Service Providers are small entities.
50. We have included small incumbent LECs in this present RFA
analysis. As noted above, a ``small business'' under the RFA is one
that, inter alia, meets the pertinent small business size standard
(e.g., a telephone communications business having 1,500 or fewer
employees), and ``is not dominant in its field of operation.'' The
SBA's Office of Advocacy contends that, for RFA purposes, small
incumbent LECs are not dominant in their field of operation because any
such dominance is not ``national'' in scope. We have therefore included
small incumbent LECs in this RFA analysis, although we emphasize that
this RFA action has no effect on Commission analyses and determinations
in other, non-RFA contexts.
51. Interexchange Carriers (IXCs). Neither the Commission nor the
SBA has developed a definition for Interexchange Carriers. The closest
NAICS Code category is Wired Telecommunications Carriers as defined
above. The applicable size standard under SBA rules is that such a
business is small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees. U.S. Census data
for 2012 indicates that 3,117 firms operated during that year. Of that
number, 3,083 operated with fewer than 1,000 employees. According to
internally developed Commission data, 359 companies reported that their
primary telecommunications service activity was the provision of
interexchange services. Of this total, an estimated 317 have 1,500 or
fewer employees. Consequently, the Commission estimates that the
majority of IXCs are small entities.
52. Local Resellers. The SBA has developed a small business size
standard for the category of Telecommunications Resellers. The
Telecommunications Resellers industry comprises establishments engaged
in purchasing access and network capacity from owners and operators of
telecommunications networks and reselling wired and wireless
telecommunications services (except satellite) to businesses and
households. Establishments in this industry resell telecommunications;
they do not operate transmission facilities and infrastructure. Mobile
virtual network operators (MVNOs) are included in this industry. Under
that size standard, such a business is small if it has 1,500 or fewer
employees. Census data for 2012 show that 1,341 firms provided resale
services during that year. Of that number, all operated with fewer than
1,000 employees. Thus, under this category and the associated small
business size standard, the majority of these resellers can be
considered small entities.
53. Toll Resellers. The Commission has not developed a definition
for Toll Resellers. The closest NAICS Code Category is
Telecommunications Resellers. The Telecommunications Resellers industry
comprises establishments engaged in purchasing access and network
capacity from owners and operators of telecommunications networks and
reselling wired and wireless telecommunications services (except
satellite) to businesses and households. Establishments in this
industry resell telecommunications; they do not operate transmission
facilities and infrastructure. Mobile virtual network operators (MVNOs)
are included in this industry. The SBA has developed a small business
size standard for the category of Telecommunications Resellers. Under
that size standard, such a business is small if it has 1,500 or fewer
employees. Census data for 2012 show that 1,341 firms provided resale
services during that year. Of that number, 1,341 operated with fewer
than 1,000 employees. Thus, under this category and the associated
small business size standard, the majority of these resellers can be
considered small entities. According to Commission data, 881 carriers
have reported that they are engaged in the provision of toll resale
services. Of this total, an estimated 857 have 1,500 or fewer
employees. Consequently, the Commission estimates that the majority of
toll resellers are small entities.
54. Other Toll Carriers. Neither the Commission nor the SBA has
developed a definition for small businesses specifically applicable to
Other Toll Carriers. This category includes toll carriers that do not
fall within the categories of interexchange carriers, operator service
providers, prepaid calling card providers, satellite service carriers,
or toll resellers. The closest applicable NAICS Code category is for
Wired Telecommunications Carriers as defined above. Under the
applicable SBA size standard, such a business is small if it has 1,500
or fewer employees. Census data for 2012 shows that there were 3,117
firms that operated that year. Of this total, 3,083 operated with fewer
than 1,000 employees. Thus, under this category and the associated
small business size standard, the majority of Other Toll Carriers can
be considered small. According to internally developed Commission data,
284 companies reported that their primary telecommunications service
activity was the provision of other toll carriage. Of these, an
estimated 279 have 1,500 or fewer employees. Consequently, the
Commission estimates that most Other Toll Carriers are small entities.
55. Prepaid Calling Card Providers. The SBA has developed a
definition for small businesses within the category of
Telecommunications Resellers. Under that SBA definition, such a
business is small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees. According to the
Commission's Form 499 Filer Database, 500 companies reported that they
were engaged in the provision of prepaid calling cards. The Commission
does not have data regarding how many of these 500 companies have 1,500
or fewer employees. Consequently, the Commission estimates that there
are 500 or fewer prepaid calling card providers that may be affected by
the rules.
56. Wireless Telecommunications Carriers (except Satellite). This
industry comprises establishments engaged in operating and maintaining
switching and transmission facilities to provide communications via the
airwaves. Establishments in this industry have spectrum licenses and
provide services using that spectrum, such as cellular services, paging
services, wireless internet access, and wireless video services. The
appropriate size standard under SBA rules is that such a business is
small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees. For this industry, U.S.
Census data for 2012 show that there were 967 firms that operated for
the entire year. Of this total, 955 firms had employment of 999 or
fewer employees and 12 had employment of 1000 employees or more. Thus
under this category and the associated size standard, the Commission
estimates that the majority of wireless telecommunications carriers
(except satellite) are small entities.
57. The Commission's own data--available in its Universal Licensing
System--indicate that, as of October 25, 2016, there are 280 Cellular
licensees that may be affected by our actions today. The Commission
does not know how many of these licensees are small, as the Commission
does not collect that information for these types of entities.
Similarly, according to internally developed Commission data, 413
carriers reported that they were engaged in the provision of wireless
telephony, including cellular service, Personal Communications Service,
and Specialized Mobile Radio Telephony services. Of this total, an
estimated 261
[[Page 30637]]
have 1,500 or fewer employees, and 152 have more than 1,500 employees.
Thus, using available data, we estimate that the majority of wireless
firms can be considered small.
58. Wireless Communications Services. This service can be used for
fixed, mobile, radiolocation, and digital audio broadcasting satellite
uses. The Commission defined ``small business'' for the wireless
communications services (WCS) auction as an entity with average gross
revenues of $40 million for each of the three preceding years, and a
``very small business'' as an entity with average gross revenues of $15
million for each of the three preceding years. The SBA has approved
these definitions.
59. Wireless Telephony. Wireless telephony includes cellular,
personal communications services, and specialized mobile radio
telephony carriers. As noted, the SBA has developed a small business
size standard for Wireless Telecommunications Carriers (except
Satellite). Under the SBA small business size standard, a business is
small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees. According to Commission data,
413 carriers reported that they were engaged in wireless telephony. Of
these, an estimated 261 have 1,500 or fewer employees and 152 have more
than 1,500 employees. Therefore, a little less than one third of these
entities can be considered small.
60. Cable and Other Subscription Programming. This industry
comprises establishments primarily engaged in operating studios and
facilities for the broadcasting of programs on a subscription or fee
basis. The broadcast programming is typically narrowcast in nature
(e.g., limited format, such as news, sports, education, or youth-
oriented). These establishments produce programming in their own
facilities or acquire programming from external sources. The
programming material is usually delivered to a third party, such as
cable systems or direct-to-home satellite systems, for transmission to
viewers. The SBA has established a size standard for this industry
stating that a business in this industry is small if it has 1,500 or
fewer employees. The 2012 Economic Census indicates that 367 firms were
operational for that entire year. Of this total, 357 operated with less
than 1,000 employees. Accordingly we conclude that a substantial
majority of firms in this industry are small under the applicable SBA
size standard.
61. Cable Companies and Systems (Rate Regulation). The Commission
has developed its own small business size standards for the purpose of
cable rate regulation. Under the Commission's rules, a ``small cable
company'' is one serving 400,000 or fewer subscribers nationwide.
Industry data indicate that there are currently 4,600 active cable
systems in the United States. Of this total, all but eleven cable
operators nationwide are small under the 400,000-subscriber size
standard. In addition, under the Commission's rate regulation rules, a
``small system'' is a cable system serving 15,000 or fewer subscribers.
Current Commission records show 4,600 cable systems nationwide. Of this
total, 3,900 cable systems have fewer than 15,000 subscribers, and 700
systems have 15,000 or more subscribers, based on the same records.
Thus, under this standard as well, we estimate that most cable systems
are small entities.
62. Cable System Operators (Telecom Act Standard). The
Communications Act also contains a size standard for small cable system
operators, which is ``a cable operator that, directly or through an
affiliate, serves in the aggregate fewer than 1 percent of all
subscribers in the United States and is not affiliated with any entity
or entities whose gross annual revenues in the aggregate exceed
$250,000,000.'' There are approximately 52,403,705 cable video
subscribers in the United States today. Accordingly, an operator
serving fewer than 524,037 subscribers shall be deemed a small operator
if its annual revenues, when combined with the total annual revenues of
all its affiliates, do not exceed $250 million in the aggregate. Based
on available data, we find that all but nine incumbent cable operators
are small entities under this size standard. We note that the
Commission neither requests nor collects information on whether cable
system operators are affiliated with entities whose gross annual
revenues exceed $250 million. Although it seems certain that some of
these cable system operators are affiliated with entities whose gross
annual revenues exceed $250 million, we are unable at this time to
estimate with greater precision the number of cable system operators
that would qualify as small cable operators under the definition in the
Communications Act.
63. All Other Telecommunications. The ``All Other
Telecommunications'' industry is comprised of establishments that are
primarily engaged in providing specialized telecommunications services,
such as satellite tracking, communications telemetry, and radar station
operation. This industry also includes establishments primarily engaged
in providing satellite terminal stations and associated facilities
connected with one or more terrestrial systems and capable of
transmitting telecommunications to, and receiving telecommunications
from, satellite systems. Establishments providing internet services or
voice over internet protocol (VoIP) services via client-supplied
telecommunications connections are also included in this industry. The
SBA has developed a small business size standard for ``All Other
Telecommunications,'' which consists of all such firms with gross
annual receipts of $32.5 million or less. For this category, U.S.
Census data for 2012 show that there were 1,442 firms that operated for
the entire year. Of these firms, a total of 1,400 had gross annual
receipts of less than $25 million. Thus a majority of ``All Other
Telecommunications'' firms potentially may be affected by our action
can be considered small.
D. Description of Projected Reporting, Recordkeeping, and Other
Compliance Requirements for Small Entities
64. The NPRM proposes and seeks comment on rule changes that will
affect LECs and intermediate access providers, including CEA providers.
The NPRM proposes rules to further limit or eliminate the occurrence of
access arbitrage, including access stimulation, which could reduce
potential reporting requirements. One possible result of the proposed
rules would be greater availability of direct connections between IXCs
and access-stimulating LECs to avoid the use of intervening third
parties, including CEA providers, and thus create more efficient and
economical network connections. Direct connections would also likely
reduce recordkeeping requirements. Specifically, we propose amending
our rules to allow access-stimulating LECs to choose either to be
financially responsible for the delivery of calls to their networks or
to accept direct connections from IXCs or from intermediate access
providers of the IXC's choosing. The proposed rules also contain
notification requirements for access-stimulating LECs, which may impact
small entities. Some of these requirements may also involve tariff
changes.
65. The NPRM also seeks comment on other actions the Commission
could take to further discourage or eliminate access arbitrage
activity. Rules which achieve these objectives could potentially affect
recordkeeping and reporting requirements.
[[Page 30638]]
E. Steps Taken To Minimize the Significant Economic Impact on Small
Entities, and Significant Alternatives Considered
66. The RFA requires an agency to describe any significant,
specifically small business, alternatives that it has considered in
reaching its proposed approach, which may include the following four
alternatives (among others): (1) The establishment of differing
compliance or reporting requirements or timetables that take into
account the resources available to small entities; (2) the
clarification, consolidation, or simplification of compliance and
reporting requirements under the rules for such small entities; (3) the
use of performance rather than design standards; and (4) an exemption
from coverage of the rule, or any part thereof, for such small
entities.
67. This NPRM invites comment on a number of proposals and
alternatives to modify or adopt access arbitrage rules and on the
legality of access stimulation generally. The Commission has found
these arbitrage practices inefficient and to ultimately increase
consumer telecommunications rates. The NPRM proposes rules to further
limit or eliminate the occurrence of access stimulation as well as
other access arbitrage in turn promoting the efficient function of the
nation's telecommunications network. We believe that if companies are
able to operate with greater efficiency this will benefit the
communications network as a whole, and its users, by allowing companies
to increase their investment in broadband deployment. Thus, we propose
to adopt rules to give access-stimulating LECs two choices about how
they connect to IXCs. First, an access-stimulating LEC can choose to be
financially responsible for calls delivered to its networks so it,
rather than IXCs, pays for the delivery of calls to its end office or
the functional equivalent. Or, second, instead of accepting this
financial responsibility, an access-stimulating LEC can choose to
accept direct connections from either the IXC or an intermediate access
provider of the IXC's choosing. In the alternative, we seek comment on
moving all traffic bound for an access-stimulating LEC to bill-and-
keep. The NPRM also seeks comment on potential revisions to the
definition of access stimulation, in particular to address intermediate
access providers. The record in this proceeding suggests additional
access arbitrage activities are occurring, including: (1) Use of
intermediate access providers by Commercial Mobile Radio Carriers; (2)
mileage pumping; and (3) daisy chaining. Comment is sought on how best
to address these activities. The NPRM seeks comment on the costs and
benefits of these proposals. Providing carriers, especially small
carriers, with options will enable them to best assess the financial
effects on their operation allowing them to determine how best to
respond.
68. The NPRM also seeks comment on other actions we can take to
further discourage or eliminate access arbitrage activity. Comment is
sought on alternatives to our proposal that could be considered to
achieve our objectives with potentially less impact on small entities.
F. Federal Rules That May Duplicate, Overlap, or Conflict With the
Proposed Rules
69. None.
VI. Ordering Clauses
70. Accordingly, it is ordered that, pursuant to sections 1, 2,
4(i), 201-206, 214, 218-220, 251, 252, 254, 256, 303(r), and 403 of the
Communications Act of 1934, as amended, and section 706 of the
Telecommunications Act of 1996, 47 U.S.C. 151, 152, 154(i), 201-206,
218-220, 251, 252, 254, 256, 303(r), and 403, and Sec. 1.1 of the
Commission's rules, 47 CFR 1.1, this Notice of Proposed Rulemaking is
adopted.
71. It is further ordered that pursuant to applicable procedures
set forth in Sec. Sec. 1.415 and 1.419 of the Commission's rules, 47
CFR 1.415, 1.419, interested parties may file comments on this Notice
of Proposed Rulemaking on or before July 20, 2018 and reply comments on
or before August 3, 2018.
72. It is further ordered that the Commission's Consumer and
Governmental Affairs Bureau, Reference Information Center, shall send a
copy of the Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, including the Initial
Regulatory Flexibility Analysis, to the Chief Counsel for Advocacy of
the Small Business Administration.
List of Subjects in 47 CFR Part 51
Common carriers, Communications.
Federal Communications Commission.
Marlene Dortch,
Secretary, Office of the Secretary.
Proposed Rules
For the reasons discussed in the preamble, the Federal
Communications Commission proposes to amend 47 CFR part 51 as follows:
PART 51--INTERCONNECTION
0
1. The authority citation for part 51 continues to read as follows:
Authority: 47 U.S.C. 151-55, 201-05, 207-09, 218, 220, 225-27,
251-54, 256, 271, 303(r), 332, 1302.
0
2. Amend Sec. 51.903 by adding paragraphs (k), (l), and (m) to read as
follows:
Sec. 51.903 Definitions.
* * * * *
(k) Access Stimulation has the same meaning as that term is defined
in Sec. 61.3(bbb) of this chapter.
(l) Intermediate Access Provider means any entity that carries or
processes traffic at any point between the final Interexchange Carrier
in a call path and the carrier providing End Office Access Service.
(m) Interexchange Carrier means a telecommunications carrier that
uses the exchange access or information access services of another
telecommunications carrier for the provision of telecommunications.
0
3. Add Sec. 51.914 to read as follows:
Sec. 51.914 Additional provisions applicable to Access Stimulation
traffic.
(a) Notwithstanding any other provision of the Commission's rules,
if a local exchange carrier is engaged in Access Stimulation, it shall
within 45 days of commencing Access Stimulation, or by [date 45 days
after the effective date of the final rule], whichever is later:
(1)(i) Not bill any affected Interexchange Carrier or any
Intermediate Access Provider for the terminating switched access tandem
switching or any terminating switched access transport charges for any
traffic between such local exchange carrier's terminating end office or
equivalent and the associated access tandem switch; and
(ii) Assume financial responsibility for the applicable
Intermediate Access Provider terminating tandem switching and
terminating switched transport access charges relating to traffic bound
for the access-stimulating local exchange carrier; or
(2) Upon request of an Interexchange Carrier for direct-trunked
transport service, provision and enable direct-trunked transport
service to either the Interexchange Carrier or an Intermediate Access
Provider of the Interexchange Carrier's choosing within [period of time
to be determined] of such a request.
(b) Notwithstanding any other provision of the Commission's rules,
if a local exchange carrier is engaged in
[[Page 30639]]
Access Stimulation, it shall within 45 days of commencing Access
Stimulation, or by [date 45 days after effective date of the final
rule], whichever is later, notify in writing all Intermediate Access
Providers which it subtends and Interexchange Carriers with which it
does business of the following:
(1) That it is a local exchange carrier engaged in Access
Stimulation;
(2) That it will either:
(i) Obtain and pay for terminating access services from
Intermediate Access Providers for such traffic as of that date; or
(ii) Offer direct-trunked transport service to any affected
Interexchange Carrier (or to an Intermediate Access Provider of the
Interexchange Carrier's choosing); and
(3) To the extent that the local exchange carrier engaged in Access
Stimulation intends to comply with paragraph (a) of this section
through electing the option described in paragraph (a)(2) of this
section, designate where on its network it will accept the requested
direct connection.
(c) Nothing in this section creates an independent obligation for a
local exchange carrier to construct new facilities other than, as
necessary, adding switch trunk ports.
(d) In the event that an Intermediate Access Provider receives
notice under paragraph (b) of this section that a local exchange
carrier engaged in Access Stimulation will be obtaining and paying for
terminating access service from such Intermediate Access Provider, an
Intermediate Access Provider shall not bill Interexchange Carriers
terminating tandem switching and terminating switched transport access
for traffic bound for such local exchange carrier but, instead bill
such local exchange carrier for such services.
(e) Notwithstanding any provision of this section, any carrier that
is not itself engaged in Access Stimulation, as that term is defined in
Sec. 61.3(bbb) of this chapter, but serves as an Intermediate Access
Provider with respect to traffic bound for an access-stimulating local
exchange carrier, shall not itself be deemed a local exchange carrier
engaged in Access Stimulation or be affected by this rule other than
paragraph (d) of this section.
0
4. Amend Sec. 51.917 by revising paragraph (c) to read as follows:
Sec. 51.917 Revenue recovery for Rate-of-Return Carriers.
* * * * *
(c) Adjustment for Access Stimulation activity. 2011 Rate-of-Return
Carrier Base Period Revenue shall be adjusted to reflect the removal of
any increases in revenue requirement or revenues resulting from Access
Stimulation activity the Rate-of-Return Carrier engaged in during the
relevant measuring period. A Rate-of-Return Carrier should make this
adjustment for its initial July 1, 2012, tariff filing, but the
adjustment may result from a subsequent Commission or court ruling.
* * * * *
[FR Doc. 2018-13699 Filed 6-28-18; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6712-01-P