Regulation of Business Data Services for Rate-of-Return Local Exchange Carriers, 22923-22938 [2018-10338]
Download as PDF
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 96 / Thursday, May 17, 2018 / Proposed Rules
I. Executive Order 13211: Actions That
Significantly Affect Energy Supply,
Distribution, or Use
This action is not subject to Executive
Order 13211, because it is not a
significant regulatory action under
Executive Order 12866.
J. National Technology Transfer and
Advancement Act (NTTAA)
List of Subjects in 40 CFR Part 300
Environmental protection, Air
pollution control, Chemicals, Hazardous
substances, Hazardous waste,
Intergovernmental relations, Natural
resources, Oil pollution, Penalties,
Reporting and recordkeeping
requirements, Superfund, Water
pollution control, Water supply.
amozie on DSK3GDR082PROD with PROPOSALS
Authority: 33 U.S.C. 1321(d); 42 U.S.C.
9601–9657; E.O. 13626, 77 FR 56749, 3CFR,
2013 Comp., p. 306; E.O. 12777, 56 FR 54757,
3 CFR, 1991 Comp., p.351; E.O. 12580, 52 FR
2923, 3 CFR, 1987 Comp., p.193.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:48 May 16, 2018
Jkt 244001
Regulation of Business Data Services
for Rate-of-Return Local Exchange
Carriers
In this document, the
Commission proposes to allow rate-ofreturn carriers receiving universal
service support under the Alternative
Connect America Cost Model (A–CAM)
to voluntarily migrate their lower speed
circuit-based business data service
(BDS) offerings to incentive regulation.
It also seeks comment on whether to
remove ex ante pricing regulation from
these carriers’ higher speed BDS
offerings and on whether further
regulatory relief is warranted for these
carriers’ lower-speed circuit-based BDS
in areas deemed competitive by a
potential competitive market test.
Additionally, the document proposes to
allow other rate-of-return carriers
receiving fixed support to opt into the
same incentive regulation proposed for
A–CAM carriers. Finally, the
Commission seeks comment on
proposed rule changes that would
implement the proposals made in this
document, including corrections to
inaccuracies contained in its current
rules.
SUMMARY:
The EPA believes the human health or
environmental risk addressed by this
action will not have potential
disproportionately high and adverse
human health or environmental effects
on minority, low-income or indigenous
populations because it does not affect
the level of protection provided to
human health or the environment. As
discussed in Section I.C. of the
preamble to this action, the NPL is a list
of national priorities. The NPL is
intended primarily to guide the EPA in
determining which sites warrant further
investigation to assess the nature and
extent of public health and
environmental risks associated with a
release of hazardous substances,
pollutants or contaminants. The NPL is
of only limited significance as it does
not assign liability to any party. Also,
placing a site on the NPL does not mean
that any remedial or removal action
necessarily need be taken.
BILLING CODE 6560–50–P
[WC Docket No. 17–144; FCC 18–46]
Federal Communications
Commission.
ACTION: Proposed rule.
K. Executive Order 12898: Federal
Actions To Address Environmental
Justice in Minority Populations and
Low-Income Populations
[FR Doc. 2018–10466 Filed 5–16–18; 8:45 am]
47 CFR Parts 1, 32, 51, 61, and 69
AGENCY:
This rulemaking does not involve
technical standards.
Dated: May 9, 2018.
Barry N. Breen,
Acting Assistant Administrator, Office of
Land and Emergency Management.
FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS
COMMISSION
Comments are due on or before
June 18, 2018; reply comments are due
on or before July 2, 2018. Parties that
believe this document may contain new
or modified information collection
requirements may submit written
Paperwork Reduction Act (PRA)
comments to the Office of Management
and Budget (OMB), and other interested
parties on or before July 16, 2018.
ADDRESSES: You may submit comments,
identified by WC Docket No. 17–144, by
any of the following methods:
• Federal Communications
Commission’s Website: https://
apps.fcc.gov/ecfs//. Follow the
instructions for submitting comments.
• People with Disabilities: Contact the
FCC to request reasonable
accommodations (accessible format
documents, sign language interpreters,
CART, etc.) by email: FCC504@fcc.gov
or phone: 202–418–0530 or TTY: 888–
835–5322.
For detailed instructions for
submitting comments and additional
information on the rulemaking process,
DATES:
PO 00000
Frm 00041
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
22923
see the SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION
section of this document.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
Justin Faulb, Wireline Competition
Bureau, Pricing Policy Division at 202–
418–1589 or via email at Justin.Faulb@
fcc.gov.
For additional information concerning
any potential information collection
requirements contained in this
document, send an email to PRA@
fcc.gov or contact Nicole Ongele at
Nicole.Ongele@fcc.gov.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: This is a
summary of the Commission’s Notice of
Proposed Rulemaking (NPRM), WC
Docket No. 17–144; FCC 18–46, adopted
on April 17, 2018 and released on April
18, 2018. The full-text of this document
may be found at the following internet
address: https://apps.fcc.gov/edocs_
public/attachmatch/FCC-18-46A1.doc.
Pursuant to §§ 1.415 and 1.419 of the
Commission’s rules, 47 CFR 1.415,
1.419, interested parties may file
comments and reply comments on or
before the dates indicated on the first
page of this document in Dockets WC
17–144. Comments may be filed using
the Commission’s Electronic Comment
Filing System (ECFS).
• Electronic Filers: Comments may be
filed electronically using the internet by
accessing the ECFS: https://apps.fcc.gov/
ecfs/.
• Paper Filers: Parties who choose to
file by paper must file an original and
one copy of each filing. If more than one
docket or rulemaking number appears in
the caption of this proceeding, filers
must submit two additional copies for
each additional docket or rulemaking
number.
Filings can be sent by hand or
messenger delivery, by commercial
overnight courier, or by first-class or
overnight U.S. Postal Service mail. All
filings must be addressed to the
Commission’s Secretary: Office of the
Secretary, Federal Communications
Commission.
• All hand-delivered or messengerdelivered paper filings for the
Commission’s Secretary must be
delivered to FCC Headquarters at 445
12th St. SW, Room TW–A325,
Washington, DC 20554. The filing hours
are 8:00 a.m. to 7:00 p.m. All hand
deliveries must be held together with
rubber bands or fasteners. Any
envelopes and boxes must be disposed
of before entering the building.
• Commercial overnight mail (other
than U.S. Postal Service Express Mail
and Priority Mail) must be sent to 9050
Junction Drive, Annapolis Junction, MD
20701.
• U.S. Postal Service first-class,
Express, and Priority mail must be
E:\FR\FM\17MYP1.SGM
17MYP1
22924
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 96 / Thursday, May 17, 2018 / Proposed Rules
addressed to 445 12th Street SW,
Washington, DC 20554.
People with Disabilities: To request
materials in accessible formats for
people with disabilities (braille, large
print, electronic files, audio format),
send an email to fcc504@fcc.gov or call
the Consumer & Governmental Affairs
Bureau at 202–418–0530 (voice), 202–
418–0432 (TTY).
Synopsis
amozie on DSK3GDR082PROD with PROPOSALS
I. Introduction
1. The Commission has long
recognized that, because it promotes
efficiency and reduces regulatory
burdens, incentive regulation is
preferable to rate-of-return regulation.
Therefore, in a series of steps over the
last three decades, the Commission
provided incentives to encourage
incumbent local exchange carriers
(LECs) to move from rate-of-return
regulation to incentive regulation. In
this NPRM, we take more steps along
that path by proposing to allow rate-ofreturn carriers that receive universal
service support under the Alternative
Connect America Cost Model (A–CAM)
to voluntarily migrate their lower speed
business data services (BDS) offerings to
incentive regulation. Because A–CAM
carriers that elect to move away from
rate-of-return regulation for their BDS
offerings (electing A–CAM carriers) will
no longer need to provide cost-based
justification for their rates, we propose
to relieve them of burdensome costbased pricing regulation, including the
obligation to conduct cost studies for
purposes of ratemaking. At the same
time, because we recognize that ex ante
pricing regulation is of limited use—and
often harmful—in a dynamic and
increasingly competitive market, we
seek comment on identifying areas
served by electing A–CAM carriers that
are sufficiently competitive that their
lower speed BDS offerings should be
relieved of ex ante pricing regulation,
and we seek comment on whether to
relieve electing A–CAM carriers’ higher
speed BDS offerings from ex ante
pricing regulation. And, because there
are other rate-of-return carriers that
receive model-based or fixed support,
and would benefit from less
burdensome regulation, we propose to
provide the same relief to those carriers
as we propose to provide to A–CAM
carriers. Taken together we expect these
actions will spur entry, innovation, and
competition in the affected BDS
markets.
II. Background
2. We start from the premise that
incentive regulation encourages carriers
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:48 May 16, 2018
Jkt 244001
to be efficient by granting them at least
a share of profits obtained from cost
reductions and allowing them to more
aggressively serve consumers (including
by reducing prices) in the face of
competitive pressures. By contrast, rateof-return regulation provides incentives
for firms to ‘‘pad’’ their rate base and to
make inefficiently high use of capital
inputs. Additionally, rate-of-return
regulation requires carriers to account
for the costs they incur in providing
service to justify their rates and
universal service support and thus
unavoidably involves substantial
regulatory burdens.
3. In 1990, the Commission began the
process of shifting away from cost-based
regulation by adopting price cap rules
that govern how the largest incumbent
LECs establish their interstate access
charges. Price cap regulation was
intended to avoid the counterproductive
incentives of rate-of-return regulation in
part by divorcing the annual rate
adjustments from the actual costs of
each individual LEC, and in part by
adjusting the cap based on actual
industry productivity experience. In
more recent years, a number of midsize
carriers have voluntarily converted from
rate-of-return to price cap regulation.
4. In 2011, as part of comprehensive
reform and modernization of the
universal service and intercarrier
compensation systems, the Commission
adopted rate caps for switched access
services for rate-of-return carriers,
thereby removing switched access
services from rate-of-return regulation.
In 2016, the Commission gave rate-ofreturn carriers the option of receiving
forward looking model-based support
from the high-cost universal service
support program, the A–CAM, designed
to estimate the cost of operating and
maintaining an efficient modern
network. More than 200 carriers opted
to receive A–CAM support which
eliminated the need for those carriers to
conduct cost studies to quantify the
amount of high-cost support they
receive. The Commission observed that
‘‘the election of model-based support
places those carriers in a different
regulatory paradigm’’ and that
‘‘[e]ffectively, the carriers that choose to
take the voluntary path to the model are
electing incentive regulation for
common line offerings.’’ As a result,
rate-of-return carriers that elected the
A–CAM support option are currently
subject to rate-of-return regulation and
the attendant requirement to conduct
cost studies only for their BDS offerings.
5. In 2017, ITTA and USTelecom
(together, Petitioners) filed a joint
petition requesting that the Commission
allow A–CAM carriers and other rate-of-
PO 00000
Frm 00042
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
return carriers that receive model-based
support to opt into the regulatory
framework for BDS that the Commission
recently adopted for price cap carriers.
The Petition explains that for such
carriers, ‘‘continued compliance with
rate-o[f]-return-based rate regulation
. . . entails significant costs.’’ It further
explains that because carriers that
receive universal service support based
on a cost model no longer have costbased switched access charges, ‘‘the
need to perform annual cost studies
now applies only with respect to BDS.’’
It also claims that rate-of-return
regulation deters investment in
networks and harms competition. The
Wireline Competition Bureau (Bureau)
sought and received comment on the
Petition. A number of commenters
support the Petition, arguing that cost
savings and lighter touch pricing
regulation of model-based carriers’ BDS
would spur competition, incentivize
investment, benefit consumers, and
eliminate unnecessary administrative
burdens. Other commenters expressed
concerns, including whether sufficient
competition exists in A–CAM study
areas to justify reduced regulation.
6. In addition to facilitating rate-ofreturn carriers’ move to incentive
regulation, the Commission has taken
major steps to reduce regulation for
carriers that face competition. Given the
inherent inefficiencies of regulation, the
Commission relies on competition to the
extent possible to ensure carriers’ rates
and practices are just and reasonable. In
1999, the Commission granted pricing
flexibility to price cap carriers that
provided service in areas where carriers
could demonstrate threshold levels of
deployment by competitive providers.
The Pricing Flexibility Order adopted
competitive triggers designed to
measure the extent to which
competitors had made irreversible, sunk
investment in collocation and transport
facilities. The Commission gave price
cap carriers that satisfied those triggers
the flexibility to offer BDS at
unregulated rates through generally
available and individually negotiated
tariffs. In addition, starting in 2007,
upon finding that competitive providers
for BDS services existed in the relevant
price cap areas, the Commission granted
a number of price cap incumbent LECs
forbearance from dominant carrier
regulation, including tariffing and price
cap regulation, for their newer packetbased broadband services. These
forbearance orders concluded that a
number of competing providers exist for
broadband BDS. They also concluded
that forbearance from burdensome
regulations when competition exists
E:\FR\FM\17MYP1.SGM
17MYP1
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 96 / Thursday, May 17, 2018 / Proposed Rules
amozie on DSK3GDR082PROD with PROPOSALS
increases the amount of competition in
the marketplace, ensuring that rates and
practices for services are just,
reasonable, and not unreasonably
discriminatory.
7. The BDS Order the Commission
adopted last year took another step
toward reducing regulation in response
to the growth of competition. In that
order, the Commission found that
reducing government intervention and
allowing market forces to continue
working would further spur entry,
innovation, and competition in BDS
markets served by price cap carriers.
The Commission applied ex ante rate
regulation ‘‘only where competition is
expected to materially fail to ensure just
and reasonable rates’’ and stated its
preference to rely ‘‘on competition
rather than regulation, wherever
purchasers can realistically turn to a
supplier beyond the incumbent LEC.’’
Based on the record before it, the
Commission found that, on balance,
competition was sufficient to ensure just
and reasonable rates for packet-based
business data services, TDM transport
services, and higher bandwidth (i.e.
above DS3) TDM services (including
OCn services) in areas served by price
cap carriers. It also adopted a
competitive market test for TDM end
user channel terminations in price cap
areas and refrained from ex ante pricing
regulation of those services in areas
deemed competitive by that test.
III. Path Forward For Lower Speed
Services
8. We seek comment on a regulatory
framework that would provide electing
A–CAM carriers a path to allow a move
from rate-of-return regulation to a more
efficient system of incentive regulation
for their TDM transport and end user
channel terminations at speeds at or
below a DS3. In so doing, we propose
to require that each A–CAM carrier’s
decision about whether to move their
BDS offerings out of rate-of-return
regulation be made on an all-or-nothing
basis for all of an A–CAM carrier’s study
areas that receive A–CAM support. We
also invite comment on what would be
an appropriate market analysis for these
lower speed services and on a
competitive market test that would
allow us to distinguish between markets
that are sufficiently competitive so as
not to warrant the burdens of ex ante
pricing regulation from those that are
not. Although the sections below focus
on A–CAM carriers, because we are
proposing to allow other rate-of-return
carriers that receive model-based or
other types of fixed support the
opportunity to elect the same or similar
lighter-touch BDS regulation that we
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:48 May 16, 2018
Jkt 244001
propose for A–CAM carriers, we also
seek comment on providing a path
forward for regulating such carriers’
BDS offerings. As commenters respond
to the requests for comment below, we
encourage discussion of how such a
path forward could work for other such
rate-of-return carriers.
A. Incentive Regulation for Lower
Capacity TDM Transport and End User
Channel Termination Services
9. We propose to allow electing A–
CAM carriers to convert their lower
capacity TDM BDS offerings to an
incentive regulatory approach modelled
on the rules the Commission adopted
for price cap carriers’ lower speed BDS
in noncompetitive areas, while still
allowing such carriers to be subject to
the switched access rate transition and
the Eligible Recovery rules applicable to
rate-of-return carriers. We propose to
allow conversion to incentive regulation
for TDM transport and end user channel
termination services offered at speeds at
or below a DS3, as well as other
generally lower speed non-packet-based
services that are commonly considered
special access services. Are there other
special access offerings by rate-of-return
carriers that we should include in the
incentive regulation option for A–CAM
carriers? For example, are there any
telecommunications service
components associated with either
residential digital subscriber line
services or dedicated internet access
services that would qualify as special
access services that we should also
allow to migrate to incentive regulation?
We anticipate that this approach will
encourage competition for BDS in areas
served by electing A–CAM carriers and
reduce unnecessary regulatory burdens
on electing A–CAM carriers. We seek
comments on this proposal, including
on the benefits and costs of this
approach.
10. The Commission has consistently
acknowledged that incentive regulation
can foster appropriate incentives for
carriers to be efficient and to innovate.
Under price cap regulation, as opposed
to cost-based regulation, carriers have
the incentive to become more efficient,
to reduce costs, and to innovate as a
means of increasing their profits.
Moreover, an appropriate X-factor and
periodic review by the Commission can
ensure that carriers share some or all of
these efficiencies with their customers.
We invite parties to identify with
specificity any short-comings in the
proposal and to suggest alternatives that
could achieve the objectives more
efficiently. Given the well-recognized
benefits of incentive regulation, we also
seek comment on whether we should
PO 00000
Frm 00043
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
22925
make this election mandatory for all A–
CAM carriers.
1. Relieving Electing A–CAM Carriers of
Rate-of-Return Regulation for Their
Lower Speed TDM BDS Offerings
11. We propose to relieve electing A–
CAM carriers of a variety of regulatory
obligations that pertain to rate-of-return
regulation, including the obligation to
perform cost studies. Rate-of-return
carriers are required by our rules to
perform relatively burdensome cost
studies to support their rate
development. Petitioners and other
commenters identify elimination of cost
studies as a primary benefit of allowing
A–CAM carriers to elect incentive
regulation. We invite parties to quantify
the burdens of preparing cost studies
(including costs and/or hours of labor)
and comment on whether cost studies
impose any special burdens on smaller
carriers. We also seek comment on
whether data from A–CAM carriers’ cost
studies are necessary in the performance
of any Commission regulatory function.
If so, will the benefits of the data
collected from electing A–CAM carriers’
cost studies outweigh the burden of
requiring them to continue to provide
that data when they are no longer
offering cost-based services? Are there
other, less burdensome ways of
collecting the relevant data from
electing A–CAM carriers that we should
explore? Are there other issues we need
to address before relieving A–CAM
carriers of the burden of cost studies? If
so, how shall we address them?
12. We also propose to allow electing
A–CAM carriers pricing flexibility for
their lower capacity TDM services
similar to that granted by the
Commission in the BDS Order to price
cap carriers in their provision of lower
capacity TDM services in counties
deemed noncompetitive by the
competitive market test we adopted for
price cap carriers. We propose to allow
electing A–CAM carriers to offer term
and volume discounts and contractbased services for their TDM transport
and end user channel termination
services offered at speeds at or below a
DS3. Electing A–CAM carriers would be
required to maintain generally available
tariffed rates subject to incentive
regulation for these lower speed TDM
transport and end user channel
terminations, and other special access
services included in their tariffs. We
seek comment on these proposals.
13. We also propose to allow electing
A–CAM carriers to remain in the NECA
traffic-sensitive tariff for switched
access services, and to continue to be
subject to the switched access rate cap
provisions of section 51.909 and the
E:\FR\FM\17MYP1.SGM
17MYP1
amozie on DSK3GDR082PROD with PROPOSALS
22926
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 96 / Thursday, May 17, 2018 / Proposed Rules
Eligible Recovery rules in section 51.917
of the Commission’s rules. We propose
to require electing A–CAM carriers to
remove their special access services
from the NECA traffic-sensitive tariff.
We seek comment on these proposals.
14. We recognize that our proposed
approach for electing A–CAM carriers
treats TDM transport differently than
the BDS Order does for price cap
carriers. While the Commission found
TDM transport to be competitive in
price cap areas generally, here we
propose to allow electing A–CAM
carriers to convert lower speed TDM
transport services to incentive
regulation but not to immediately
eliminate ex ante pricing regulation for
them. We propose this different
approach given that competition for
such services may not be as robust in
the less dense, more rural areas that A–
CAM carriers typically serve. We seek
comment on this aspect of our proposal,
and on what data exist to confirm or
invalidate our assumption. The
Commission observed in the BDS Order
that competitive transport services are
typically deployed at locations where
sufficient demand is aggregated to
enable a competitor to justify
investment. To what extent is there
sufficient aggregated demand in A–CAM
areas to justify the deployment of
competitive transport? Are there
instances where demand for TDM
transport services may be increasing,
creating the precondition for
competitive entry in the future?
Alternatively, has the overall decline in
demand for TDM services also affected
the demand for lower speed TDM
transport services in A–CAM areas?
Finally, we seek comment on allowing
additional regulatory relief for A–CAM
carriers’ TDM transport offered at
speeds at or below a DS3 in areas
deemed competitive by a competitive
market test we seek comment on below.
15. We do not propose to transition
electing A–CAM carriers to incentive
regulation for switched access services.
The transition provisions for switched
access rates and Eligible Recovery rules
for rate-of-return carriers adopted by the
USF/ICC Transformation Order are well
established, have been upheld on
appeal, and have been partially
implemented; disrupting these
transitions would likely impose
additional costs and increase
uncertainty, deterring investment and
deployment. We also seek comment on
the benefits and costs of our proposed
approach. The Petition sought an
‘‘exception’’ to § 61.41 of the
Commission’s rules (the so-called ‘‘all or
nothing’’ rule), which requires all of a
price cap carrier’s study areas and rates,
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:48 May 16, 2018
Jkt 244001
including those of affiliates and carriers
it purchases or merges with, to be
subject to price cap regulation. We
propose to amend § 61.41 to create an
exception for the alternative regulatory
structure we propose in this NPRM, and
we seek comment on this proposal. Are
there any other rules we should
consider waiving or amending in the
context of this proceeding?
2. Implementing Optional Incentive
Regulation for Lower Capacity TDM
Services
16. In this section, we make specific
proposals regarding the terms of the
incentive regulation we propose to
adopt for electing A–CAM carriers and
seek comment on these proposals.
a. Election
17. We propose to require carriers that
elect to move off rate-of-return
regulation for their BDS services to
move to incentive regulation at the
holding company level for study areas
in all states that elected to receive A–
CAM support rather than electing on an
individual carrier or study area basis, as
proposed by Petitioners. Requiring
election at the holding company level
will ensure cost savings from the
elimination of annual cost studies to be
realized by all affiliated carriers electing
A–CAM support. Carriers have already
had the opportunity to elect between A–
CAM and cost-based support at a statewide level. Allowing A–CAM carriers to
elect regulatory treatment at a more
disaggregated level would appear to be
inconsistent with the underlying
premise of price caps, which assumed a
broad representation of carrier
operations to provide a basis for
establishing an industry-wide
productivity factor. Currently, there are
262 A–CAM companies when
calculated at the state level and 207
when calculated at the holding
company level. We invite parties to
comment on the proposed level of
election. Parties believing the proposed
holding company level is too high
should explain why a more
disaggregated level would be in the
public interest. Any explanation should
include concrete examples of why the
proposed level would preclude a
significant number of A–CAM carriers
from electing incentive regulation.
Parties should address whether other
aspects of the proposal could be
modified to make the proposed level of
election more acceptable.
18. We propose to make incentive
regulation for electing A–CAM carriers
effective on the July 1st following
adoption of an order in this proceeding,
which is the deadline for the annual
PO 00000
Frm 00044
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
access tariff filing. Using July 1st will
simplify the tariffing process for
implementing any change and is
consistent with the price cap rules’ use
of the prior calendar-year demand data
for their price cap calculations. We
invite parties to comment on this
proposal, and to suggest other timing
options that may work, identifying the
benefits and drawbacks of such
proposals. The proposals should
address the periods for determining cost
and demand for electing A–CAM
carriers. We also invite parties to
comment on whether we should allow
a one-time opportunity to elect, or
whether additional election
opportunities should be allowed. If
more than one opportunity to elect is
offered, what should the timing be for
any additional election opportunities?
19. We have recently proposed
making a second A–CAM offer. In the
event that additional rate-of-return
carriers become A–CAM carriers, we
propose that they may elect to adopt
incentive regulation at the next annual
tariff filing date that follows their
election. We also propose to allow the
new electing A–CAM carriers to adopt
the other lighter touch regulatory
options that are available to electing A–
CAM carriers at that time. We invite
parties to comment on these proposals.
b. Initial Rate Levels
20. We propose to allow electing A–
CAM carriers that currently file their
own tariffed rates for BDS offerings to
use their existing rates to set their initial
BDS rates under incentive regulation.
The Commission used this method
when allowing rate-of-return carriers
filing their own rates to convert to price
cap regulation. The demand to be used
for the incentive regulation calculations
would be that of the previous calendar
year. The carrier would then apply the
prescribed X-factor and the inflation
factor, two variables in the
Commission’s existing formula for the
price cap index (PCI), which would
result in the proposed rates in the first
year of incentive regulation, and each
year thereafter. We invite parties to
comment on this proposal. We ask that
any party disagreeing with this
approach submit a detailed proposal for
setting initial rates, including an
explanation of why its preferred
approach would be equal to or better
than the approach we propose.
21. Establishing initial BDS rates for
electing A–CAM carriers participating
in the NECA traffic-sensitive pool is
more complicated because they are
charging a pooled rate, which does not
reflect the actual costs of the pooling
carrier. The NECA pool BDS rates are
E:\FR\FM\17MYP1.SGM
17MYP1
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 96 / Thursday, May 17, 2018 / Proposed Rules
amozie on DSK3GDR082PROD with PROPOSALS
therefore not the proper rates to use as
initial BDS rates. We therefore propose
that each electing A–CAM carrier in the
pool establish its initial BDS rates by
multiplying the NECA pool rate the
carrier has been charging by a net
contribution/recipient factor. Thus, an
A–CAM carrier with more BDS revenues
than the BDS settlements it receives
from the pool would have its pool rate
reduced commensurately. The opposite
would occur for an electing A–CAM
carrier that received more BDS
settlements than the BDS revenues it
produced. The carrier would then apply
the prescribed X-factor and the inflation
factor, which would result in the
proposed rates in the first year of
incentive regulation, and each year
thereafter. This approach avoids the
necessity of doing new cost studies for
each study area of the electing A–CAM
carriers. We invite parties to comment
on this approach. Alternatively,
commenters may suggest other
approaches, such as doing cost studies
for the preceding calendar year, or other
twelve-month period. Parties making
such alternative proposals should
address the manner in which the
alternative time period data would be
incorporated into the incentive
regulation calculations.
22. Are there other approaches we
should take in determining how electing
A–CAM carriers should establish initial
BDS rates? Are there other adjustments
that we should make to our proposed
initial rate setting process? For example,
should the initial rates be lower than
current rates because of the cost savings
electing carriers will realize by moving
to incentive regulation? If so, how much
should be shared with consumers and
how should such amount be
determined? In a 2012 waiver petition
seeking to move from rate-of-return to
price cap status, FairPoint
Communications, Inc., proposed
reducing its special access rates by a
percentage of the anticipated cost
savings. We invite parties to comment
on these issues and to suggest how such
amounts should be determined,
especially if another cost study is to be
avoided.
carriers contained in sections 61.45–48
of our rules, as appropriate, to reflect
the prescribed productivity factor, the
inflation factor, and any required
exogenous cost adjustment in the PCI, to
ensure that the Actual Price Index (API)
does not exceed the PCI, and that the
SBIs for each category or subcategory do
not exceed their upper limits. The
category and sub-category requirements
are designed to limit the degree to
which a carrier can raise rates in any
given year in an effort to avoid anticompetitive pricing. We invite parties to
comment on this proposal. Are there
other approaches we should take? Are
there other categories or sub-categories
needed for A–CAM carriers that were
not necessary for price cap carriers? We
request that parties recommending that
we modify the categories or subcategories explain why such a change
would improve the functioning of the
incentive regulation plan and/or the
BDS market and produce benefits for
consumers.
22927
warrant that the Commission increase or
decrease the X-Factor? Should the level
of the X-Factor be affected by whether
the carrier election is for all A–CAM
study areas, or made on a more
disaggregated level?
e. Exogenous Costs
27. We seek comment on the
treatment that should be accorded
exogenous costs if we allow A–CAM
carriers to elect to move to incentive
regulation. Exogenous costs are those
costs that are beyond the control of the
carrier, as determined by the
Commission. Section 61.45(d) of our
rules provides for an exogenous cost
adjustment for price cap carriers to be
apportioned on a cost-causative basis
between price cap services as a group,
and excluded services as a group.
Exogenous cost changes attributed to
price cap services are recovered from
services other than those used to
calculate the average traffic-sensitive
charge. A–CAM carriers have been
removed from rate-of-return regulation
d. Productivity Factor and Measure of
for universal service purposes and for
Inflation
interstate access services other than
24. Consistent with the BDS Order, we BDS. We invite parties to address how
also propose to adopt an X-factor of two the principle of cost causation should be
applied in determining the amount of
percent to reflect the productivity
growth that electing A–CAM carriers are any exogenous costs to be assigned to
the BDS basket for electing A–CAM
likely to experience in the provision of
carriers. We propose that exogenous
these services relative to productivity
costs be allocated based on a ratio of
growth in the overall economy in the
BDS revenues to total revenues from all
foreseeable future and to use Gross
Domestic Product-Price Index (GDP–PI) regulated services and A–CAM
universal service support payments. We
as the measure of inflation that electing
invite parties to address whether some
A–CAM carriers will use in their PCI
other basis would be preferable,
calculations. We do not propose to
including the rationale for the
incorporate a consumer productivity
alternative approach.
dividend (CPD) adjustment into this Xfactor. Based on the industry-wide
f. Low-End Adjustment
analysis provided in the BDS Order and
28. Consistent with the BDS Order, we
Petitioners’ proposal that we use a two
percent X-Factor, we believe an X-factor propose to adopt a low-end adjustment
mechanism to provide an appropriate
of two percent will ensure just and
backstop to ensure that electing A–CAM
reasonable rates for BDS offered by
electing A–CAM carriers, and that use of carriers are not subject to protracted
periods of low earnings. Failure to
the GDP–PI is appropriate. We seek
include any adjustment for such
comment on this proposal.
circumstances could harm customers as
25. Are there reasons we should use
well as shareholders of such a carrier as
a different productivity factor for
a below-normal rate-of-return over a
electing A–CAM providers than we use
prolonged period could threaten the
for price cap carriers? We request that
carrier’s ability to raise the capital
any party proposing a different
c. Special Access Basket, Categories and productivity factor or measure of
necessary to provide modern, efficient
Subcategories
inflation factor describe with specificity services to customers. The low-end
adjustment mechanism would permit a
23. Consistent with the BDS Order, we how their proposed X-Factor is derived
one-time adjustment to a single year’s
propose to retain the special access
and why it would be a better forecast of
BDS rates to avoid back-to-back annual
basket, categories and subcategories,
the expected pattern of growth than
earnings below a set benchmark. If an
and the attendant rules governing the
what we propose herein.
electing A–CAM carrier’s BDS earnings
26. We also seek comment on the
allowed annual adjustments. We
fall below the low-end adjustment mark
propose to require each electing A–CAM extent to which the voluntary nature of
in a base year period, it would be
carrier to initialize its PCI for the special the election interacts with the
entitled to adjust its rates upward to
appropriate level of the X-Factor. For
access basket and associated service
target earnings to the benchmark. We
band indices (SBIs) at 100 and to use the example, are there relationships
propose that, consistent with past
between different factors that could
rate adjustment rules for price cap
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:48 May 16, 2018
Jkt 244001
PO 00000
Frm 00045
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
E:\FR\FM\17MYP1.SGM
17MYP1
22928
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 96 / Thursday, May 17, 2018 / Proposed Rules
amozie on DSK3GDR082PROD with PROPOSALS
practice, the low-end adjustment
benchmark should be set 100 basis
points below the authorized rate of
return for rate-of-return carriers. We
propose that electing A–CAM carriers
that exercise downward pricing
flexibility (for example, by entering into
a contract tariff with a customer), or
elect the option to use generally
accepted accounting practices (GAAP)
rather than the Part 32 Uniform System
of Accounts as set forth in our recent
Part 32 Accounting Order, will be
ineligible for a low-end adjustment.
29. We invite interested parties to
comment on the proposal to adopt a
low-end adjustment mechanism. We ask
parties to comment on whether this
measure will ensure that electing A–
CAM carriers have the opportunity to
attract sufficient capital. We note that an
A–CAM carrier would have to present
cost data to support a claim for a lowend adjustment. Because eliminating the
need for cost studies is one of the
driving objectives behind Petitioners’
proposal, we ask parties to comment on
whether there are alternative ways to
make the required determinations short
of performing a full cost study. Parties
offering suggestions should explain the
proposed mechanism in sufficient detail
that a comparison to the results of a cost
study can be made. We also seek
comment on the appropriateness of
setting the benchmark for the low-end
adjustment at 100 basis points below the
authorized rate of return for rate-ofreturn carriers. We note that this
proposal would allow the benchmark to
track the gradual reduction in the
authorized rate-of-return as it transitions
down.
g. Cost Assignment and Jurisdictional
Separations Rules
30. Pursuant to section 10 of the Act,
and to implement our new incentive
regulation for those A–CAM carriers
that elect incentive regulation, we
propose to forbear from application of
our cost assignment rules, including
jurisdictional separations requirements.
Consistent with our previous
forbearance orders for price cap carriers,
we propose to define cost assignment
rules to include the rules governing the
assignment of costs and revenues by
carriers. We seek comment on our
proposed definition.
31. In providing similar forbearance to
price cap carriers, the Commission
observed that such rules ‘‘were
developed when the ILECs’ interstate
rates and many of their intrastate rates
were set under rate-based, cost-ofservice regulation. The Commission has
explained that ‘because price cap
regulation severs the direct link between
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:48 May 16, 2018
Jkt 244001
regulated costs and prices, a carrier is
not able automatically to recoup
misallocated non-regulated costs by
raising basic service rates,’ thus
reducing incentives to shift nonregulated costs to regulated services.’’
Does the same reasoning for forbearance
apply to A–CAM carriers electing
incentive regulation? Will the operation
of the incentive regulation rules we
propose make enforcement of the cost
assignment and separations rules
unnecessary to ensure just, reasonable
and not unjustly or unreasonably
discriminatory charges, practices,
classifications, and regulations, or make
enforcement of those rules unnecessary
to protect consumers from unjust,
unreasonable, and unjustly or
unreasonably discriminatory rates,
practices, classifications, and
regulations? Is enforcement of such
regulations unnecessary to protect
consumers? Would forbearance be
consistent with the public interest and
would the reduction of regulatory
burdens improve market
competitiveness?
32. We further propose to condition
any grant of forbearance from
application of the cost assignment and
jurisdictional separations rules for an
electing A–CAM carrier that froze their
separations category relationships on its
conducting a cost study for the
preceding calendar year. The A–CAM
carrier would then adjust the initialized
BDS rates determined pursuant to the
procedures described above by the
results of the cost study. We invite
parties to comment on this proposal and
to identify any constraints that should
be placed on application of the cost
study results to the development of
revised access charges, including BDS
rates. For example, should a carrier be
limited in the extent it may adjust the
relative price relationships between
business data services that may be
established?
33. Above, we propose procedures for
electing A–CAM carriers to use in
establishing initial BDS rates under
incentive regulation that assume other
factors remained unchanged. Forbearing
from cost allocation and jurisdictional
separations requirements for A–CAM
carriers electing incentive regulation,
however, would change one of the
controlled factors. We invite comment
on what adjustments, if any, we should
allow an A–CAM carrier that elects to
freeze its category relationships to make
to its rates to ensure that its BDS rates
are just and reasonable pursuant to
section 201 of the Act.
PO 00000
Frm 00046
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
h. GAAP Accounting
34. We propose to allow electing A–
CAM carriers to use GAAP for keeping
their accounts, should they choose to do
so. The Commission recently revised the
Part 32 rules to allow price cap LECs to
elect to use GAAP in recording and
reporting their financial data, subject to
two targeted accounting requirements.
Electing carriers may either (a) calculate
an Implementation Rate Difference
between the attachment rates calculated
by the price cap carrier under the
Uniform System of Accounts (USOA)
and under GAAP as of the last full year
preceding the carrier’s initial opting-out
of Part 32 USOA accounting
requirements; or (b) comply with GAAP
accounting for all purposes other than
those associated with setting pole
attachment rates while continuing to
use the Part 32 accounts and procedures
necessary to establish and evaluate pole
attachment rates. Electing carriers must
adjust their annually computed GAAPbased rates by the Implementation Rate
Difference for a period of 12 years after
the election. This frees price cap carriers
from having to maintain two sets of
books: One for financial reporting
purposes consistent with GAAP and one
for regulatory reporting purposes
consistent with the accounting
requirements of Part 32. For the same
reasons, we propose to allow electing
A–CAM carriers to have the option to
use GAAP. We propose to require
electing A–CAM carriers that choose to
use GAAP accounting to be subject to
the same data provisioning
requirements as price cap carriers,
including the requirements relating to
the calculation of pole attachment rates.
As a result, such carriers will have to
determine an Implementation Rate
Difference to apply in calculating their
pole attachment rates. We seek
comment on this proposal. Are there
other issues with allowing electing A–
CAM carriers to use GAAP accounting
that we should consider?
B. Providing a Path To Relieve Electing
A–CAM Carriers of Ex Ante Pricing
Regulation for Lower Speed End User
Channel Terminations and TDM
Transport in Competitive Areas
35. We seek comment on whether we
should adopt a competitive market test
(CMT) to assess the availability of actual
and likely competitive options in the
provision of transport and last-mile
services in areas served by electing A–
CAM carriers and to remove from ex
ante pricing regulation DS1 and DS3
end user channel terminations, TDM
transport at speeds at or below a DS3,
and other generally lower speed BDS
E:\FR\FM\17MYP1.SGM
17MYP1
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 96 / Thursday, May 17, 2018 / Proposed Rules
provided (or some subset of these
services) by electing A–CAM carriers in
areas that the CMT finds competitive. If
so, what should be the elements of such
a test and what are the costs and
benefits of adopting such a test? We also
seek comment on whether we should
use different metrics and/or different
tests to measure the competitiveness of
lower speed end user channel
terminations as compared to lower
speed TDM transport services.
36. If we adopt a CMT for electing A–
CAM carriers, should we use the CMT
the Commission adopted in the BDS
Order for price cap carriers (the existing
CMT) as a starting point? The existing
CMT features two prongs, based on data
from price cap study areas. The first
measures whether 50 percent of the
locations with BDS demand in a county
are within a half-mile of a location that
was served by a competitive provider,
based on the 2015 Collection. The
second uses Form 477 data to measure
whether a cable operator offers a
minimum of 10/1 Mbps broadband
service in 75 percent of the census
blocks in the county. If either prong is
satisfied, that county is deemed
competitive for price cap carriers’ BDS.
Below, we seek comment on several
options for a CMT for electing A–CAM
carriers, some of which include the use
of the existing CMT. Beside the options
we offer below, are there other options
we should consider if we choose to
adopt a CMT? What are the costs and
benefits of each?
amozie on DSK3GDR082PROD with PROPOSALS
1. CMT Options
a. Rerun the Second Prong of the
Existing CMT Using 477 Data for A–
CAM Areas
37. First, we seek comment on
adopting a CMT that uses only a version
of the second prong of the existing CMT
using data from areas served by A–CAM
carriers. Under this approach, we would
rerun the second prong of the existing
CMT using FCC Form 477 data only
from electing A–CAM carriers’ study
areas. We would then deem
competitive, for purposes of relieving
electing A–CAM carriers’ lower speed
TDM BDS services from ex ante pricing
regulation, any county where a cable
operator or other competitive provider
offers a minimum of 10/1 Mbps
broadband service in 75 percent of the
census blocks in the portion of the
county served by an electing A–CAM
carrier. This approach has the benefit of
simplicity. It would allow us to use FCC
Form 477 data that we regularly collect
and would identify areas served by
electing A–CAM carriers that
competitors or potential competitors
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:48 May 16, 2018
Jkt 244001
already serve. Because we would not be
using the first prong of the existing
CMT, there would be no need to
conduct a BDS data collection for A–
CAM carriers akin to the 2015
Collection. For a variety of reasons, we
are not inclined to adopt an approach
that would require another such largescale data collection. The burdens
associated with such a data collection
would be substantial for A–CAM
carriers and other providers of data, and
could significantly delay Commission
action without corresponding benefits.
However, we invite comment on this
issue. Because of the lack of cable
service in many rate-of-return study
areas, we recognize that this test will
likely result in very few A–CAM
counties being deemed competitive.
Does that suggest this test is accurate in
identifying competition in A–CAM
areas? Are there other costs and benefits
to this approach that we should
consider?
b. Use the Results of the Existing CMT
38. Petitioners propose that we apply
the existing CMT to electing A–CAM
carriers’ BDS offerings. Under this
proposal, an electing A–CAM carrier’s
lower speed TDM BDS offerings would
be relieved of ex ante pricing regulation
in those counties that have already been
deemed competitive by the existing
CMT. Petitioners recognize that there
are 78 purely rate-of-return counties that
were not analyzed by the existing CMT.
They propose to use the second prong
of the existing CMT to determine
whether those counties should be
considered competitive. Petitioners
argue that this approach would involve
minimal administrative and compliance
burdens and would avoid the need for
revising and re-running the CMT for
electing A–CAM carriers or analyzing
any additional data.
39. We seek comment on Petitioners’
proposed approach. The existing CMT
was developed for price cap carriers’
service areas and involved analysis of
competition only in price cap areas. The
Commission did not consider
competition in A–CAM markets. Is an
analysis of existing or potential
competition in price cap areas of a
county an appropriate way to determine
whether competition or potential
competition exists in areas of that
county served by an electing A–CAM
carrier? Is it likely to result in
deregulating lower speed TDM-based
BDS services offered by electing A–
CAM carriers in counties where such
carriers will not face competitive
pressure in pricing those services? Are
there other benefits or drawbacks to this
approach that we should consider?
PO 00000
Frm 00047
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
22929
c. Apply a Modified Two-Prong CMT to
Areas Served by Electing A-CAM
Carriers
40. Another option would be to adopt
a CMT for electing A–CAM carriers
using prongs similar to those of the
existing CMT, but using data specific to
areas served by electing A–CAM
carriers. We seek comment on this
approach. We recognize that for
purposes of the first prong of the new
CMT, this approach would require a
data collection sufficient to allow us to
identify for each county served by an
electing A–CAM carrier whether 50
percent of the locations with BDS
demand in that part of the county are
within a half-mile of a location that was
served by a competitive provider. Such
a collection could be limited to electing
A–CAM carriers and their competitors.
Nonetheless, we have reservations about
the relative costs and benefits of
conducting such a data collection. And,
the current record is split on whether
we should consider a new data
collection. We seek comment on how to
most efficiently collect relevant data
and on whether the burdens of such a
data collection outweigh the benefits.
We also seek comment on other benefits
and drawbacks to this option.
d. Adopt a CMT Based on a Market
Analysis Specific to Areas Served by A–
CAM Carriers
41. A fourth option is to create a
whole new CMT based on a competitive
market analysis specific to BDS services
in areas served by electing A–CAM
carriers. Petitioners argue that the BDS
market analysis conducted in the BDS
Order with respect to price cap areas
applies equally to rate-of-return areas
served by A–CAM carriers. We seek
comment on Petitioners’ argument.
42. In the BDS Order, the Commission
conducted a broad, data-driven, multifaceted market analysis based on a
comprehensive data collection to
evaluate the extent of competition for
BDS in price cap areas. The
Commission’s market analysis was
informed by, but not limited to,
traditional antitrust principles, such as
the market power analysis performed by
U.S. antitrust agencies. The Commission
analyzed the product market,
geographic market, barriers to entry, and
other characteristics of price cap BDS
markets.
43. If we conduct a new market
analysis, should it be similar to the
market analysis conducted by the
Commission in the BDS Order as a
precondition to determining whether
competition is sufficient to warrant
lighter touch regulation in certain BDS
E:\FR\FM\17MYP1.SGM
17MYP1
amozie on DSK3GDR082PROD with PROPOSALS
22930
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 96 / Thursday, May 17, 2018 / Proposed Rules
markets? If we do conduct a new market
analysis, we propose to consider
product and geographic markets,
competitive entry, and other market
attributes to ascertain the extent to
which nearby potential BDS competitors
are likely to temper price, resulting in
reasonably competitive prices over the
short- to medium-term (i.e., up to three
to five years). Would this be the right
approach to assessing the level of
competition for BDS in A–CAM areas?
What other approaches should we
consider taking? How should we
analyze transport under our market
analysis? Would a competitive market
analysis give us sufficient basis to go
beyond the incremental deregulation of
lower speed transport that we propose
above? We ask commenters to support
their positions with data that would
help us determine whether markets are
sufficiently competitive to warrant
deregulatory treatment.
44. Data for a Market Analysis. If we
conduct a market analysis, what
relevant data are available and what are
the potential utility and limitations of
the available data? Should we review
FCC Form 477 data on mass market
broadband service to determine the
extent to which they serve as evidence
of the presence of network facilities
capable of delivering reasonably
competitive BDS over the short- to
medium-term (three to five years) in A–
CAM areas? We seek comment on the
data, methodologies, and modeling used
to develop the A–CAM study area
boundaries, including state-level
location density data, the A–CAM
model, and geocoded location data
submitted to USAC and the extent they
can assist us in analyzing the BDS
market in A–CAM areas.
45. To the extent the Commission’s
existing data sources are insufficient, we
seek data from commenters on facilitiesbased BDS providers serving A–CAM
areas that would help us to ascertain
markets with reasonably competitive
conditions to justify lighter touch
regulatory treatment. Are there existing
data similar to data collected as part of
the 2015 Collection that would help us
better understand or estimate the
location of BDS demand in A–CAM
areas, including consumers and
business locations served (or readily
served) by BDS, as well as data on
market structure, demand, pricing, and
competitive pressures in those areas?
Does similar data exist that could
identify BDS demand for transport in
A–CAM areas? If we have to collect new
data, what data should we collect and
what is the most efficient way to collect
it? Does the cost of conducting and
analyzing such a data collection
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:48 May 16, 2018
Jkt 244001
outweigh the benefits of conducting an
A–CAM specific market analysis?
46. Product Market. If we conduct a
new market analysis, should we use the
same analysis to define the product
market for lower speed TDM end user
channel terminations and transport in
A–CAM areas as we used to define the
product market for BDS in price cap
areas in the BDS Order? We anticipate
that the product market for BDS in A–
CAM areas will closely resemble the
BDS product market delineated in the
BDS Order for price cap areas and seek
comment on this belief and on potential
differences that may exist between the
two types of markets. Despite these
similarities, we recognize that there may
be differences between price cap areas
and A–CAM areas that may affect the
BDS product markets in these areas. Are
there products that were marketed or
supplied to BDS customers in price cap
areas that are not in demand, marketed,
or otherwise supplied in A–CAM areas
as a BDS substitute, and to what extent
do products that are not in the same
BDS product market nonetheless exert
competitive pressure on prices for BDS
in A–CAM areas?
47. Geographic Market. In the BDS
Order, the Commission defined the
geographic market in terms of ‘‘the area
to which consumers can ‘practically
turn for alternative sources,’ and within
which providers can reasonably
compete.’’ Consistent with the BDS
Order, should we define the geographic
market as an area where customers have
medium-term competitive choices for
BDS based on customer locations within
a half mile of a location served over the
facilities of at least one non-incumbent
competitive provider? We encourage
commenters to provide data and
analysis to support their positions.
48. Competitive Entry. As part of our
analysis, and consistent with the BDS
Order, should we consider how varying
market characteristics impact entry by
non-incumbent competing BDS
providers in A–CAM areas, along with
evidence of entry barriers being
overcome by traditional and nontraditional competing providers? We
seek comment on identifiable market
features in A–CAM areas, including
carrier market share, number and size
distribution of competing firms, the
nature of competitors’ barriers to entry,
the availability of reasonably
substitutable services, the level of
demand elasticity, and whether a firm
controls bottleneck facilities to help us
identify where competition is sufficient
to make imposing the burdens of ex ante
pricing regulation unnecessary and
counterproductive.
PO 00000
Frm 00048
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
49. We seek comment on the number,
type, size, concentration, and market
share of nearby BDS competitors (i.e.,
within a half-mile) that operate in A–
CAM study areas, in the form of
facilities-based wired communications
network providers, that temper prices to
reasonably competitive levels in the
short- to medium-term.
50. Consistent with the BDS Order,
should we consider as part of our
market analysis the extent to which
providers and potential providers face
barriers to enter the BDS marketplace in
A–CAM areas? We seek comment on the
timeliness, likelihood, and sufficiency
of a competitor’s entry into the BDS
market in A–CAM areas. We seek
comment on the barriers facing carriers
for both lower speed TDM end user
channel terminations and transport.
How are the markets different? For
example, in the BDS Order, the
Commission found lower entry barriers
for deploying TDM transport services
than for end user channel termination
services. Is this accurate for A–CAM
carrier study areas as well? Would
buildout and entry by an entrant be
rapid enough to render incumbent LECs’
attempts to set prices above competitive
levels unprofitable? Would such entry
occur over a longer timeframe, such as
three to five years, and, if so, would that
justify taking the same light touch
regulatory approach here as taken in the
BDS Order? To what extent is market
entry profitable (and thus likely) based
on projected expenditures and revenues
from customers and potential
customers? Is the presence of a second
provider in the relevant geographic
market, whether a non-incumbent LEC
or a cable operator, sufficient to
constrain prices to competitive levels?
To what extent does the half-mile test
that was derived from the market
analysis of price cap areas relate to
demand densities in those areas that
may not be present in A–CAM areas?
Finally, we seek comment on the extent
incumbents and non-incumbent
entrants, particularly cable companies,
are upgrading or building out their
networks to sources of BDS demand in
A–CAM study areas.
2. Updating CMT Results for A–CAM
Carriers
51. The BDS Order directed the
Bureau to review the existing price cap
CMT every three years using the second
prong of the test based on Form 477
data. If we adopt a CMT for electing A–
CAM carriers, we seek comment on
whether we should conduct similar
periodic reviews of any CMT we adopt
for such carriers. For administrative
ease, should we target the timing of our
E:\FR\FM\17MYP1.SGM
17MYP1
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 96 / Thursday, May 17, 2018 / Proposed Rules
initial review of the results of a CMT for
electing A–CAM carriers to coincide
with our initial review of price cap
served areas? Under the BDS Order,
counties that were determined to be
competitive were no longer subject to
review of their status in subsequent
updates of the CMT. Should we treat A–
CAM areas similarly? If not, we seek
comment on alternatives to
grandfathering those A–CAM areas.
amozie on DSK3GDR082PROD with PROPOSALS
3. Regulation in Areas Deemed
Competitive by the CMT
52. If we adopt a CMT for areas served
by electing A–CAM carriers, consistent
with the BDS Order, we propose to
refrain from ex ante pricing regulation
for lower speed transport and TDM enduser channel terminations in areas
deemed competitive. We also seek
comment on whether forbearing from
section 203 tariffing requirements for
these services in these areas would meet
the statutory criteria of section 10 of the
Act. As we did in the BDS Order, we
recognize the continuing applicability
and importance of sections 201, 202,
and 208 of the Act to ensure that
consumers will remain protected from
unjust and unreasonable rates in areas
deemed competitive. We seek comment
on this proposal.
IV. Removing Ex Ante Pricing
Regulation From Packet-Based BDS and
TDM-Based BDS Providing Bandwidth
in Excess of a DS3
53. We also seek comment on whether
we should eliminate ex ante pricing
regulation of packet-based and TDMbased business data services providing
bandwidth in excess of a DS3 offered by
those carriers that elect to move their
lower speed BDS offerings from rate-ofreturn regulation to incentive
regulation. If so, should we provide 36
months for such a transition? If we
transition these high-speed services,
consistent with the BDS Order, we
would continue to recognize the
applicability and importance of sections
201, 202, and 208 of the Act in
protecting consumers from unjust and
unreasonable practices.
54. With respect to price cap areas,
the Commission’s market analysis did
‘‘not show compelling evidence of
market power’’ in incumbent LECs’
provision of packet-based services and
higher capacity TDM-based business
data services (in excess of the
bandwidth of a DS3), particularly for
higher bandwidth services. We seek
comment on whether these observations
offer any insights on the nature and
extent of competition in A–CAM areas.
Are markets for higher capacity TDMbased BDS offerings (above the
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:48 May 16, 2018
Jkt 244001
bandwidth of a DS3) and packet-based
services likely to be sufficiently
competitive in A–CAM areas over the
next three to five years such that the
harms of price regulation in these
markets, most notably in terms of
discouraging the extension of
competition, are likely to be greater than
any harms that may occur were we not
to regulate? Are these markets
sufficiently competitive to outweigh any
benefits of ex ante pricing regulation?
Parties are encouraged to provide
evidence to support their arguments. We
seek comment on the extent to which
Commission or other data could
facilitate our evaluation of competition
in these areas, including Form 477 mass
market broadband data, A–CAM study
area boundary data, A–CAM modeling
data, and geocoded location data
submitted to USAC. We invite
commenters to identify specific data
sources that could be useful to our
inquiry and to explain their utility.
55. The Commission also found that
sales of TDM-based BDS by price cap
carriers were declining due to product
substitution, including customer loss to
cable operators and other competitive
providers. To what extent are
purchasers substituting packet-based
services for TDM-based services in A–
CAM areas? Are TDM-based services
declining in A–CAM areas at a rate
similar to the decline in price cap areas?
The Commission found declining prices
for packet-based BDS across all
bandwidths in price cap areas to be
evidence of competitive conditions.
Have prices for packet-based BDS in A–
CAM areas also declined across all
bandwidths? Are lower bandwidth
packet-based services (at or below the
level of a DS3) experiencing price
changes in A–CAM areas as in price cap
areas?
56. We recognize that price cap
carriers’ provision of these services was
generally relieved of ex ante pricing
regulation prior to the BDS Order in a
series of forbearance decisions. In
contrast, A–CAM carriers provide these
services subject to rate-of-return
regulation. Would removing ex ante
pricing regulation for these services for
electing A–CAM carriers encourage
competitive entry and network
investment and provide an incentive for
the transition to packet-based
technologies as we found to be the case
for price cap carriers? In the foregoing,
we seek comment on the parameters of
this potential transition. Are there other
issues we should consider as we
evaluate whether to remove ex ante
pricing regulation for all packet-based
and TDM-based services providing
PO 00000
Frm 00049
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
22931
bandwidth in excess of a DS3 offered by
electing A–CAM carriers?
57. We seek comment on granting
forbearance from section 203 tariffing
requirements for A–CAM carriers’
provision of certain BDS after they elect
incentive regulation. In the BDS Order,
the Commission granted forbearance
from the application of section 203 to
each price cap LEC in its provision of
any packet-based BDS and of circuitbased BDS above the DS3 bandwidth
level. The Commission also granted
forbearance from the application of
section 203 to price cap incumbent
LECs in their provision of BDS that
comprise transport pursuant to section
69.709(a)(4) of the Commission’s rules,
and to DS1 and DS3 end user channel
termination services and any other
special access services currently tariffed
in competitive counties or in noncompetitive counties previously subject
to Phase II pricing flexibility. The
Commission concluded that ‘‘[w]here a
price cap LEC provides these services in
competitive markets, application of
section 203, including its tariffing
requirement, is not necessary to ensure
that the LEC’s charges, practices,
classifications, or regulations are just,
reasonable, and not unjustly or
unreasonably discriminatory. Nor is
application of section 203 necessary to
protect consumers.’’
58. While the Petition does not
expressly request forbearance from
tariffing requirements, we seek
comment on whether to de-tariff certain
electing A–CAM BDS offerings by
granting forbearance from section 203
tariffing obligations. We seek comment
on whether we should remove ex ante
pricing regulation of packet-based BDS
and higher capacity TDM-based services
providing bandwidth in excess of a DS3
for A–CAM carriers that elect incentive
regulation. Would forbearing from the
tariffing requirement for these services
meet the statutory criteria set by section
10 of the Act? Would de-tariffing these
services promote competitive market
conditions? Would de-tariffing reduce
compliance costs, increase regulatory
flexibility, increase incentives to invest
in innovative products and services and
thereby facilitate the technology
transitions, or otherwise be in the public
interest as the Petition asserts? If the
Commission decides to forbear from
section 203, should it mandate or
simply allow de-tariffing? Would
mandatory de-tariffing further promote
competition and drive down prices by
requiring electing carriers to negotiate
agreements to provide the de-tariffed
services that they offer?
E:\FR\FM\17MYP1.SGM
17MYP1
22932
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 96 / Thursday, May 17, 2018 / Proposed Rules
V. Transition Mechanisms
59. We seek comment on how to
transition electing A–CAM carriers and
the areas they serve if the Commission
adopts a new lighter touch regulatory
framework for their provision of BDS.
The BDS Order provided certain
mechanisms to facilitate the transition
to the new regulatory framework that it
established for price cap carriers. These
mechanisms included a thirty-six month
transition period in which de-tariffing is
permitted but not mandated, a six
month freeze of tariffed rates for enduser channel terminations in newly
deregulated counties, and a
grandfathering of existing contractual or
other long-term BDS arrangements. We
seek comment on the appropriateness of
these and other mechanisms to aid in
the transition of electing A–CAM areas
to any new regulatory framework we
establish for them. Are there other
transition issues and mechanisms that
may be unique to A–CAM carriers and
the areas they serve that would help
ensure an orderly transition? For
example, should the Commission
consider any additional mechanisms
that would facilitate transitions for
electing A–CAM carriers that participate
in NECA pooling arrangements?
amozie on DSK3GDR082PROD with PROPOSALS
VI. Other Carriers
60. We propose to offer the
opportunity to elect the same type of
regulatory relief that we propose to
provide to electing A–CAM carriers to
other rate-of-return carriers that
currently receive fixed universal service
support, rather than receiving support
based on their costs. Such carriers
include traditional rate-of-return
carriers that are affiliated with price cap
carriers and are therefore receiving
support based on the Connect America
Cost Model (CACM); rate-of-return
carriers participating in the
Commission’s ‘‘Alaska Plan’’; and
carriers that accept further offers of A–
CAM support.
61. Like A–CAM carriers, the
members of each of these three groups
of rate-of-return carriers all receive noncost-based universal service support and
therefore are routinely required to
prepare cost studies only for their BDS.
What are the costs and benefits of
relieving them of existing pricing
regulations and allowing them to elect
the type of incentive pricing regulation
we propose? Should we modify our
proposed incentive regulation in any
way to reflect differences in any of these
types of carriers’ circumstances? Are
there any other types of carriers that
should be eligible for our incentive
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:48 May 16, 2018
Jkt 244001
regulation proposal and, if so, based on
what rationale?
VII. ITTA/USTelecom Petition
62. Throughout this NPRM, we seek
comment on various aspects of the
Petition for rulemaking filed by ITTA
and USTelecom. However, the Petition
differs in some ways from what we
propose in this NPRM. Most
fundamentally, it proposes that subject
to certain conditions we simply allow
model-based carriers to elect the same
regulatory framework that the BDS
Order provided for price cap carriers. It
also proposes providing electing A–
CAM carriers an opportunity for a onetime unfreezing of category
relationships for purposes of
jurisdictional separations. To the extent
we have not already done so, we invite
comment on the Petition and each of the
proposals made therein.
VIII. Proposed Rule Changes
63. We seek comment on the
proposed rule changes that can be found
in Appendix A. Those rule changes
largely track the proposals made in this
NPRM. They also include some
corrections to what appear to be
inaccuracies in our current rules. These
proposed changes include changing (1)
the cross reference to § 61.3(aa) in
§ 51.903(g) to § 61.3(bb), (2) the cross
reference to § 61.3(ee) in § 61.41(d) to
§ 61.3(ff), (3) the cross reference to
§ 61.3(x) in § 69.114 to § 61.3(ff), and (4)
the cross reference to § 69.801(g) in
§ 69.805(a) to § 69.801(h). These cross
references have been rendered
inaccurate because of changes in the
definitions contained in § 61.3 that
occurred in other rulemaking
proceedings or because they were
incorrectly stated when added to our
rules.
IX. Procedural Matters
64. This proceeding shall be treated as
a ‘‘permit-but-disclose’’ proceeding in
accordance with the Commission’s ex
parte rules. Persons making ex parte
presentations must file a copy of any
written presentation or a memorandum
summarizing any oral presentation
within two business days after the
presentation (unless a different deadline
applicable to the Sunshine period
applies). Persons making oral ex parte
presentations are reminded that
memoranda summarizing the
presentation must (1) list all persons
attending or otherwise participating in
the meeting at which the ex parte
presentation was made, and (2)
summarize all data presented and
arguments made during the
presentation. If the presentation
PO 00000
Frm 00050
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
consisted in whole or in part of the
presentation of data or arguments
already reflected in the presenter’s
written comments, memoranda or other
filings in the proceeding, the presenter
may provide citations to such data or
arguments in his or her prior comments,
memoranda, or other filings (specifying
the relevant page and/or paragraph
numbers where such data or arguments
can be found) in lieu of summarizing
them in the memorandum. Documents
shown or given to Commission staff
during ex parte meetings are deemed to
be written ex parte presentations and
must be filed consistent with rule
1.1206(b). In proceedings governed by
Rule 1.49(f) or for which the
Commission has made available a
method of electronic filing, written ex
parte presentations and memoranda
summarizing oral ex parte
presentations, and all attachments
thereto, must be filed through the
electronic comment filing system
available for that proceeding, and must
be filed in their native format (e.g., .doc,
.xml, .ppt, searchable .pdf). Participants
in this proceeding should familiarize
themselves with the Commission’s ex
parte rules.
A. Initial Regulatory Flexibility Analysis
65. Pursuant to the Regulatory
Flexibility Act (RFA), the Commission
has prepared an Initial Regulatory
Flexibility Analysis (IRFA) of the
possible significant economic impact on
small entities of the policies and actions
considered in this Notice of Proposed
Rulemaking. The text of the IRFA is set
forth in Appendix B. Written public
comments are requested on this IRFA.
Comments must be identified as
responses to the IRFA and must be filed
by the deadlines for comment on the
Notice of Proposed Rulemaking. The
Commission’s Consumer and
Governmental Affairs Bureau, Reference
Information Center, will send a copy of
this Notice of Proposed Rulemaking,
including the IRFA, to the Chief
Counsel for Advocacy of the Small
Business Administration (SBA).
B. Paperwork Reduction Act
66. This document may contain
proposed new or modified information
collection requirements. The
Commission, as part of its continuing
effort to reduce paperwork burdens,
invites the general public and the Office
of Management and Budget (OMB) to
comment on the information collection
requirements contained in this
document, as required by the Paperwork
Reduction Act of 1995, Public Law 104–
13. In addition, pursuant to the Small
Business Paperwork Relief Act of 2002,
E:\FR\FM\17MYP1.SGM
17MYP1
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 96 / Thursday, May 17, 2018 / Proposed Rules
Public Law 107–198, we seek specific
comment on how we might further
reduce the information collection
burden for small business concerns with
fewer than 25 employees.
X. Initial Regulatory Flexibility
Analysis
amozie on DSK3GDR082PROD with PROPOSALS
67. As required by the Regulatory
Flexibility Act of 1980, as amended
(RFA), the Commission has prepared
this Initial Regulatory Flexibility
Analysis (IRFA) of the possible
significant economic impact on small
entities by the policies and rules
proposed in this Notice of Proposed
Rulemaking (NPRM). The Commission
requests written public comments on
this IRFA. Comments must be identified
as responses to the IRFA and must be
filed by the deadlines for comments
provided on the first page of the NPRM.
The Commission will send a copy of the
NPRM, including this IRFA, to the Chief
Counsel for Advocacy of the Small
Business Administration (SBA). In
addition, the NPRM and IRFA (or
summaries thereof) will be published in
the Federal Register.
C. Description and Estimate of the
Number of Small Entities to Which the
Proposed Rules Will Apply
70. The RFA directs agencies to
provide a description of, and where
feasible, an estimate of the number of
small entities that may be affected by
the proposed rules and by the rule
revisions on which the NPRM seeks
comment, if adopted. The RFA generally
defines the term ‘‘small entity’’ as
having the same meaning as the terms
‘‘small business,’’ ‘‘small organization,’’
and ‘‘small governmental jurisdiction.’’
In addition, the term ‘‘small business’’
has the same meaning as the term
‘‘small-business concern’’ under the
Small Business Act. A ‘‘small-business
concern’’ is one which: (1) Is
independently owned and operated; (2)
is not dominant in its field of operation;
and (3) satisfies any additional criteria
established by the SBA.
1. Total Small Entities
71. Small Businesses, Small
Organizations, Small Governmental
Jurisdictions. Our actions, over time,
may affect small entities that are not
easily categorized at present. We
therefore describe here, at the outset,
A. Need for, and Objectives of, the
three broad groups of small entities that
Proposed Rules
could be directly affected herein. First,
68. In this NPRM, we propose changes while there are industry specific size
standards for small businesses that are
to, and seek comment on, our rate-ofused in the regulatory flexibility
return and business data services rules
analysis, according to data from the
as they are applied to rate-of-return
SBA’s Office of Advocacy, in general a
carriers that receive universal service
small business is an independent
support based on the Alternativebusiness having fewer than 500
Connect America Cost Model (A–CAM), employees. These types of small
or under the Commission’s universal
businesses represent 99.9% of all
service support mechanism for Alaskabusinesses in the United States which
based carriers (Alaska Plan), or is an
translates to 28.8 million businesses.
affiliate of a price cap local exchange
72. Next, the type of small entity
carrier operating pursuant to a waiver of described as a ‘‘small organization’’ is
§ 61.41 of our rules. In the NPRM, the
generally ‘‘any not-for-profit enterprise
Commission proposes to adopt a form of which is independently owned and
incentive regulation for A–CAM
operated and is not dominant in its
field.’’ Nationwide, as of August 2016,
carriers’ provision of business data
there were approximately 356,494 small
services (BDS), conduct a market
organizations based on registration and
analysis to evaluate the characteristics
tax data filed by nonprofits with the
of BDS markets served by A–CAM
Internal Revenue Service (IRS).
carriers, and adopt a new lighter touch
73. Finally, the small entity described
regulatory framework for A–CAM
as a ‘‘small governmental jurisdiction’’
carriers’ BDS that in most respects
is defined generally as ‘‘governments of
parallels the framework recently
adopted for price cap carriers in the BDS cities, towns, townships, villages,
school districts, or special districts, with
Order.
a population of less than fifty
B. Legal Basis
thousand.’’ U.S. Census Bureau data
from the 2012 Census of Governments
69. The legal basis for any action that
indicates that there were 90,056 local
may be taken pursuant to this NPRM is
governmental jurisdictions consisting of
contained in sections 1, 4(i), 10, and
general purpose governments and
201(b) of the Communications Act of
special purpose governments in the
1934, as amended, 47 U.S.C. 151, 154(i), United States. Of this number there
160, and 201(b).
were 37,132 general purpose
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:48 May 16, 2018
Jkt 244001
PO 00000
Frm 00051
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
22933
governments (county, municipal and
town or township) with populations of
less than 50,000 and 12,184 special
purpose governments (independent
school districts and special districts)
with populations of less than 50,000.
The 2012 U.S. Census Bureau data for
most types of governments in the local
government category shows that the
majority of these governments have
populations of less than 50,000. Based
on these data we estimate that at least
49,316 local government jurisdictions
fall in the category of ‘‘small
governmental jurisdictions.’’
2. Broadband Internet Access Service
Providers
74. Internet Service Providers
(Broadband). Broadband internet
service providers include wired (e.g.,
cable, DSL) and VoIP service providers
using their own operated wired
telecommunications infrastructure fall
in the category of Wired
Telecommunication Carriers. Wired
Telecommunications Carriers are
comprised of establishments primarily
engaged in operating and/or providing
access to transmission facilities and
infrastructure that they own and/or
lease for the transmission of voice, data,
text, sound, and video using wired
telecommunications networks.
Transmission facilities may be based on
a single technology or a combination of
technologies. The SBA size standard for
this category classifies a business as
small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees.
U.S. Census data for 2012 show that
there were 3,117 firms that operated that
year. Of this total, 3,083 operated with
fewer than 1,000 employees.
Consequently, under this size standard
the majority of firms in this industry can
be considered small.
3. Wireline Providers
75. Wired Telecommunications
Carriers. The U.S. Census Bureau
defines this industry as ‘‘establishments
primarily engaged in operating and/or
providing access to transmission
facilities and infrastructure that they
own and/or lease for the transmission of
voice, data, text, sound, and video using
wired communications networks.
Transmission facilities may be based on
a single technology or a combination of
technologies. Establishments in this
industry use the wired
telecommunications network facilities
that they operate to provide a variety of
services, such as wired telephony
services, including VoIP services, wired
(cable) audio and video programming
distribution, and wired broadband
internet services. By exception,
establishments providing satellite
E:\FR\FM\17MYP1.SGM
17MYP1
amozie on DSK3GDR082PROD with PROPOSALS
22934
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 96 / Thursday, May 17, 2018 / Proposed Rules
television distribution services using
facilities and infrastructure that they
operate are included in this industry.’’
The SBA has developed a small
business size standard for Wired
Telecommunications Carriers, which
consists of all such companies having
1,500 or fewer employees. Census data
for 2012 show that there were 3,117
firms that operated that year. Of this
total, 3,083 operated with fewer than
1,000 employees. Thus, under this size
standard, the majority of firms in this
industry can be considered small.
76. Incumbent Local Exchange
Carriers (Incumbent LECs). Neither the
Commission nor the SBA has developed
a small business size standard
specifically for incumbent LEC services.
The closest applicable size standard
under SBA rules is for the category
Wired Telecommunications Carriers as
defined above. Under that size standard,
such a business is small if it has 1,500
or fewer employees. According to
Commission data, 3,117 firms operated
in that year. Of this total, 3,083 operated
with fewer than 1,000 employees.
Consequently, the Commission
estimates that most providers of
incumbent local exchange service are
small businesses that may be affected by
the rules and policies adopted. A total
of 1,307 firms reported that they were
incumbent local exchange service
providers. Of this total, an estimated
1,006 have 1,500 or fewer employees.
77. Competitive Local Exchange
Carriers (Competitive LECs),
Competitive Access Providers (CAPs),
Shared-Tenant Service Providers, and
Other Local Service Providers. Neither
the Commission nor the SBA has
developed a small business size
standard specifically for these service
providers. The appropriate NAICS Code
category is Wired Telecommunications
Carriers, as defined above. Under that
size standard, such a business is small
if it has 1,500 or fewer employees. U.S.
Census data for 2012 indicate that 3,117
firms operated during that year. Of that
number, 3,083 operated with fewer than
1,000 employees. Based on this data, the
Commission concludes that the majority
of Competitive LECS, CAPs, SharedTenant Service Providers, and Other
Local Service Providers, are small
entities. According to Commission data,
1,442 carriers reported that they were
engaged in the provision of either
competitive local exchange services or
competitive access provider services. Of
these 1,442 carriers, an estimated 1,256
have 1,500 or fewer employees. In
addition, 17 carriers have reported that
they are Shared-Tenant Service
Providers, and all 17 are estimated to
have 1,500 or fewer employees. Also, 72
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:48 May 16, 2018
Jkt 244001
carriers have reported that they are
Other Local Service Providers. Of this
total, 70 have 1,500 or fewer employees.
Consequently, based on internally
researched FCC data, the Commission
estimates that most providers of
competitive local exchange service,
competitive access providers, SharedTenant Service Providers, and Other
Local Service Providers are small
entities.
78. We have included small
incumbent LECs in this present RFA
analysis. As noted above, a ‘‘small
business’’ under the RFA is one that,
inter alia, meets the pertinent small
business size standard (e.g., a telephone
communications business having 1,500
or fewer employees), and ‘‘is not
dominant in its field of operation.’’ The
SBA’s Office of Advocacy contends that,
for RFA purposes, small incumbent
LECs are not dominant in their field of
operation because any such dominance
is not ‘‘national’’ in scope. We have
therefore included small incumbent
LECs in this RFA analysis, although we
emphasize that this RFA action has no
effect on Commission analyses and
determinations in other, non-RFA
contexts.
79. Interexchange Carriers (IXCs).
Neither the Commission nor the SBA
has developed a definition for
Interexchange Carriers. The closest
NAICS Code category is Wired
Telecommunications Carriers as defined
above. The applicable size standard
under SBA rules is that such a business
is small if it has 1,500 or fewer
employees. U.S. Census data for 2012
indicates that 3,117 firms operated
during that year. Of that number, 3,083
operated with fewer than 1,000
employees. According to internally
developed Commission data, 359
companies reported that their primary
telecommunications service activity was
the provision of interexchange services.
Of this total, an estimated 317 have
1,500 or fewer employees.
Consequently, the Commission
estimates that the majority of IXCs are
small entities that may be affected by
our proposed rules.
80. Local Resellers. The SBA has
developed a small business size
standard for the category of
Telecommunications Resellers. The
Telecommunications Resellers industry
comprises establishments engaged in
purchasing access and network capacity
from owners and operators of
telecommunications networks and
reselling wired and wireless
telecommunications services (except
satellite) to businesses and households.
Establishments in this industry resell
telecommunications; they do not
PO 00000
Frm 00052
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
operate transmission facilities and
infrastructure. Mobile virtual network
operators (MVNOs) are included in this
industry. Under that size standard, such
a business is small if it has 1,500 or
fewer employees. Census data for 2012
show that 1,341 firms provided resale
services during that year. Of that
number, all operated with fewer than
1,000 employees. Thus, under this
category and the associated small
business size standard, the majority of
these prepaid calling card providers can
be considered small entities.
81. Toll Resellers. The Commission
has not developed a definition for Toll
Resellers. The closest NAICS Code
Category is Telecommunications
Resellers. The Telecommunications
Resellers industry comprises
establishments engaged in purchasing
access and network capacity from
owners and operators of
telecommunications networks and
reselling wired and wireless
telecommunications services (except
satellite) to businesses and households.
Establishments in this industry resell
telecommunications; they do not
operate transmission facilities and
infrastructure. Mobile virtual network
operators (MVNOs) are included in this
industry. The SBA has developed a
small business size standard for the
category of Telecommunications
Resellers. Under that size standard, such
a business is small if it has 1,500 or
fewer employees. Census data for 2012
show that 1,341 firms provided resale
services during that year. Of that
number, 1,341 operated with fewer than
1,000 employees. Thus, under this
category and the associated small
business size standard, the majority of
these resellers can be considered small
entities. According to Commission data,
881 carriers have reported that they are
engaged in the provision of toll resale
services. Of this total, an estimated 857
have 1,500 or fewer employees.
Consequently, the Commission
estimates that the majority of toll
resellers are small entities.
82. Other Toll Carriers. Neither the
Commission nor the SBA has developed
a definition for small businesses
specifically applicable to Other Toll
Carriers. This category includes toll
carriers that do not fall within the
categories of interexchange carriers,
operator service providers, prepaid
calling card providers, satellite service
carriers, or toll resellers. The closest
applicable NAICS Code category is for
Wired Telecommunications Carriers as
defined above. Under the applicable
SBA size standard, such a business is
small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees.
Census data for 2012 show that there
E:\FR\FM\17MYP1.SGM
17MYP1
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 96 / Thursday, May 17, 2018 / Proposed Rules
amozie on DSK3GDR082PROD with PROPOSALS
were 3,117 firms that operated that year.
Of this total, 3,083 operated with fewer
than 1,000 employees. Thus, under this
category and the associated small
business size standard, the majority of
Other Toll Carriers can be considered
small. According to internally
developed Commission data, 284
companies reported that their primary
telecommunications service activity was
the provision of other toll carriage. Of
these, an estimated 279 have 1,500 or
fewer employees. Consequently, the
Commission estimates that most Other
Toll Carriers are small entities that may
be affected by rules adopted pursuant to
the Second Further Notice of Proposed
Rulemaking.
83. Operator Service Providers (OSPs).
Neither the Commission nor the SBA
has developed a small business size
standard specifically for operator
service providers. The appropriate size
standard under SBA rules is for the
category Wired Telecommunications
Carriers. Under that size standard, such
a business is small if it has 1,500 or
fewer employees. According to
Commission data, 33 carriers have
reported that they are engaged in the
provision of operator services. Of these,
an estimated 31 have 1,500 or fewer
employees and two have more than
1,500 employees. Consequently, the
Commission estimates that the majority
of OSPs are small entities.
84. Prepaid Calling Card Providers.
The SBA has developed a definition for
small businesses within the category of
Telecommunications Resellers. Under
that SBA definition, such a business is
small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees.
According to the Commission’s Form
499 Filer Database, 500 companies
reported that they were engaged in the
provision of prepaid calling cards. The
Commission does not have data
regarding how many of these 500
companies have 1,500 or fewer
employees. Consequently, the
Commission estimates that there are 500
or fewer prepaid calling card providers
that may be affected by the rules.
4. Wireless Providers—Fixed and
Mobile
85. Wireless Telecommunications
Carriers (except Satellite). This industry
comprises establishments engaged in
operating and maintaining switching
and transmission facilities to provide
communications via the airwaves.
Establishments in this industry have
spectrum licenses and provide services
using that spectrum, such as cellular
services, paging services, wireless
internet access, and wireless video
services. The appropriate size standard
under SBA rules is that such a business
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:48 May 16, 2018
Jkt 244001
is small if it has 1,500 or fewer
employees. For this industry, U.S.
Census data for 2012 show that there
were 967 firms that operated for the
entire year. Of this total, 955 firms had
employment of 999 or fewer employees
and 12 had employment of 1000
employees or more. Thus under this
category and the associated size
standard, the Commission estimates that
the majority of wireless
telecommunications carriers (except
satellite) are small entities.
86. The Commission’s own data—
available in its Universal Licensing
System—indicate that, as of October 25,
2016, there are 280 Cellular licensees
that will be affected by our actions
today. The Commission does not know
how many of these licensees are small,
as the Commission does not collect that
information for these types of entities.
Similarly, according to internally
developed Commission data, 413
carriers reported that they were engaged
in the provision of wireless telephony,
including cellular service, Personal
Communications Service, and
Specialized Mobile Radio Telephony
services. Of this total, an estimated 261
have 1,500 or fewer employees, and 152
have more than 1,500 employees. Thus,
using available data, we estimate that
the majority of wireless firms can be
considered small.
87. Wireless Communications
Services. This service can be used for
fixed, mobile, radiolocation, and digital
audio broadcasting satellite uses. The
Commission defined ‘‘small business’’
for the wireless communications
services (WCS) auction as an entity with
average gross revenues of $40 million
for each of the three preceding years,
and a ‘‘very small business’’ as an entity
with average gross revenues of $15
million for each of the three preceding
years. The SBA has approved these
definitions.
88. Wireless Telephony. Wireless
telephony includes cellular, personal
communications services, and
specialized mobile radio telephony
carriers. As noted, the SBA has
developed a small business size
standard for Wireless
Telecommunications Carriers (except
Satellite). Under the SBA small business
size standard, a business is small if it
has 1,500 or fewer employees.
According to Commission data, 413
carriers reported that they were engaged
in wireless telephony. Of these, an
estimated 261 have 1,500 or fewer
employees and 152 have more than
1,500 employees. Therefore, a little less
than one third of these entities can be
considered small.
PO 00000
Frm 00053
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
22935
5. Satellite Service Providers
89. Satellite Telecommunications
Providers. This category comprises firms
‘‘primarily engaged in providing
telecommunications services to other
establishments in the
telecommunications and broadcasting
industries by forwarding and receiving
communications signals via a system of
satellites or reselling satellite
telecommunications.’’ Satellite
telecommunications service providers
include satellite and earth station
operators. The category has a small
business size standard of $32.5 million
or less in average annual receipts, under
SBA rules. For this category, U.S.
Census Bureau data for 2012 show that
there were a total of 333 firms that
operated for the entire year. Of this
total, 299 firms had annual receipts of
less than $25 million. Consequently, we
estimate that the majority of satellite
telecommunications providers are small
entities.
6. Cable Service Providers
90. Because section 706 requires us to
monitor the deployment of broadband
using any technology, we anticipate that
some broadband service providers may
not provide telephone service.
Accordingly, we describe below other
types of firms that may provide
broadband services, including cable
companies, MDS providers, and
utilities, among others.
91. Cable and Other Subscription
Programming. This industry comprises
establishments primarily engaged in
operating studios and facilities for the
broadcasting of programs on a
subscription or fee basis. The broadcast
programming is typically narrowcast in
nature (e.g. limited format, such as
news, sports, education, or youthoriented). These establishments produce
programming in their own facilities or
acquire programming from external
sources. The programming material is
usually delivered to a third party, such
as cable systems or direct-to-home
satellite systems, for transmission to
viewers. The SBA has established a size
standard for this industry stating that a
business in this industry is small if it
has 1,500 or fewer employees. The 2012
Economic Census indicates that 367
firms were operational for that entire
year. Of this total, 357 operated with
less than 1,000 employees. Accordingly
we conclude that a substantial majority
of firms in this industry are small under
the applicable SBA size standard.
92. Cable Companies and Systems
(Rate Regulation). The Commission has
developed its own small business size
standards for the purpose of cable rate
E:\FR\FM\17MYP1.SGM
17MYP1
amozie on DSK3GDR082PROD with PROPOSALS
22936
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 96 / Thursday, May 17, 2018 / Proposed Rules
regulation. Under the Commission’s
rules, a ‘‘small cable company’’ is one
serving 400,000 or fewer subscribers
nationwide. Industry data indicate that
there are currently 4,600 active cable
systems in the United States. Of this
total, all but eleven cable operators
nationwide are small under the 400,000subscriber size standard. In addition,
under the Commission’s rate regulation
rules, a ‘‘small system’’ is a cable system
serving 15,000 or fewer subscribers.
Current Commission records show 4,600
cable systems nationwide. Of this total,
3,900 cable systems have fewer than
15,000 subscribers, and 700 systems
have 15,000 or more subscribers, based
on the same records. Thus, under this
standard as well, we estimate that most
cable systems are small entities.
93. Cable System Operators (Telecom
Act Standard). The Communications
Act also contains a size standard for
small cable system operators, which is
‘‘a cable operator that, directly or
through an affiliate, serves in the
aggregate fewer than 1 percent of all
subscribers in the United States and is
not affiliated with any entity or entities
whose gross annual revenues in the
aggregate exceed $250,000,000.’’ There
are approximately 52,403,705 cable
video subscribers in the United States
today. Accordingly, an operator serving
fewer than 524,037 subscribers shall be
deemed a small operator if its annual
revenues, when combined with the total
annual revenues of all its affiliates, do
not exceed $250 million in the
aggregate. Based on available data, we
find that all but nine incumbent cable
operators are small entities under this
size standard. The Commission neither
requests nor collects information on
whether cable system operators are
affiliated with entities whose gross
annual revenues exceed $250 million.
Although it seems certain that some of
these cable system operators are
affiliated with entities whose gross
annual revenues exceed $250 million,
we are unable at this time to estimate
with greater precision the number of
cable system operators that would
qualify as small cable operators under
the definition in the Communications
Act.
94. All Other Telecommunications.
‘‘All Other Telecommunications’’ is
defined as follows: This U.S. industry is
comprised of establishments that are
primarily engaged in providing
specialized telecommunications
services, such as satellite tracking,
communications telemetry, and radar
station operation. This industry also
includes establishments primarily
engaged in providing satellite terminal
stations and associated facilities
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:48 May 16, 2018
Jkt 244001
connected with one or more terrestrial
systems and capable of transmitting
telecommunications to, and receiving
telecommunications from, satellite
systems. Establishments providing
internet services or voice over internet
protocol (VoIP) services via clientsupplied telecommunications
connections are also included in this
industry. The SBA has developed a
small business size standard for ‘‘All
Other Telecommunications,’’ which
consists of all such firms with gross
annual receipts of $32.5 million or less.
For this category, census data for 2012
show that there were 1,442 firms that
operated for the entire year. Of these
firms, a total of 1,400 had gross annual
receipts of less than $25 million.
Consequently, we estimate that the
majority of All Other
Telecommunications firms are small
entities that might be affected by our
action.
7. Electric Power Generators,
Transmitters, and Distributors
95. Electric Power Generators,
Transmitters, and Distributors. This
U.S. industry is comprised of
establishments that are primarily
engaged in providing specialized
telecommunications services, such as
satellite tracking, communications
telemetry, and radar station operation.
This industry also includes
establishments primarily engaged in
providing satellite terminal stations and
associated facilities connected with one
or more terrestrial systems and capable
of transmitting telecommunications to,
and receiving telecommunications from,
satellite systems. Establishments
providing internet services or voice over
internet protocol (VoIP) services via
client-supplied telecommunications
connections are also included in this
industry. The closest applicable SBA
category is ‘‘All Other
Telecommunications’’. The SBA’s small
business size standard for ‘‘All Other
Telecommunications,’’ consists of all
such firms with gross annual receipts of
$32.5 million or less. For this category,
U.S. Census data for 2012 show that
there were 1,442 firms that operated for
the entire year. Of these firms, a total of
1,400 had gross annual receipts of less
than $25 million. Consequently, we
estimate that under this category and
the associated size standard the majority
of these firms can be considered small
entities.
D. Description of Projected Reporting,
Recordkeeping, and Other Compliance
Requirements for Small Entities
96. This NPRM proposes changes to,
and seeks comment on, the
PO 00000
Frm 00054
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
Commission’s rate-of-return and
business data services rules. The
objective of the proposed modifications
is to reduce the unnecessary regulatory
burdens and inflexibility of rate-ofreturn regulation for BDS services for
A–CAM carriers, which are for the most
part small businesses. These rule
modifications would provide additional
incentives for competitive entry,
network investment and the migration
to IP-based network technologies and
services. The NPRM seeks comment on
proposed rules that would generally
reduce compliance requirements for A–
CAM carriers that choose to opt into the
new incentive regulation and regulatory
framework for the provision of BDS.
97. Under the Commission’s rate-ofreturn rules, rates for business data
services are based on costs derived from
carrier-specific cost studies which
represent a significant compliance
burden for A–CAM carriers relative to
their overall revenues. The NPRM
proposes to transition these carriers to a
form of incentive regulation that will
enable these LECs to significantly
reduce these compliance costs. The
NPRM also proposes a new regulatory
framework for A–CAM carriers’ BDS
that would in many cases eliminate ex
ante pricing regulation and tariffing
requirements for carriers electing
incentive regulation.
E. Steps Taken To Minimize the
Significant Economic Impact on Small
Entities, and Significant Alternatives
Considered
98. The RFA requires an agency to
describe any significant alternatives that
it has considered in reaching its
proposed approach, which may include
the following four alternatives (among
others): (1) The establishment of
differing compliance or reporting
requirements or timetables that take into
account the resources available to small
entities; (2) the clarification,
consolidation, or simplification of
compliance and reporting requirements
under the rules for such small entities;
(3) the use of performance rather than
design standards; and (4) an exemption
from coverage of the rule, or any part
thereof, for such small entities.
99. The rule changes proposed by the
NPRM would reduce the economic
impact of the Commission’s rules on A–
CAM carriers that elect incentive
regulation in the following ways.
Electing A–CAM carriers would no
longer be required to prepare annual
cost studies to justify their BDS rates.
Such carriers would also be freed of ex
ante pricing regulation for many of their
BDS offerings, including packet-based
BDS, circuit-based BDS above a DS3
E:\FR\FM\17MYP1.SGM
17MYP1
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 96 / Thursday, May 17, 2018 / Proposed Rules
bandwidth (about 45 Mbps) such as
OCn services, and circuit-based end
user channel terminations (e.g. DS1 and
DS3) in geographic areas deemed to be
competitive by a competitive market
test. These proposed rule changes
represent alternatives to the
Commission’s current rules that would
significantly minimize the economic
impact of those rules on electing A–
CAM LECs. Finally, we seek comment
as to any additional economic burden
incurred by small entities that may
result from the rule changes proposed in
the NPRM.
F. Federal Rules That May Duplicate,
Overlap, or Conflict With the Proposed
Rules
100. None.
101. Accordingly, it is ordered,
pursuant to sections 1, 4(i), 10, and
201(b) of the Communication Act of
1934, as amended, 47 U.S.C. 151, 154(i),
160, and 201(b) that the Petition for
Rulemaking filed by ITTA and
USTelecom in this proceeding is
granted to the extent described herein.
102. It is further ordered, pursuant to
sections 1, 4(i), 10, and 201(b) of the
Communication Act of 1934, as
amended, 47 U.S.C. 151, 154(i), 160,
and 201(b) that this Notice of Proposed
Rulemaking is adopted.
103. It is further ordered, Pursuant to
Section 220(i) of the Communications
Act, 47 U.S.C. 220(i), that notice be
given to each state commission of the
above rulemaking proceeding, and that
the Secretary shall serve a copy of this
NPRM on each state commission.
104. It is further ordered that the
Commission’s Consumer and
Governmental Affairs Bureau, Reference
Information Center, shall send a copy of
this Notice of Proposed Rulemaking,
including the Initial Regulatory
Flexibility Analysis, to the Chief
Counsel for Advocacy of the Small
Business Administration.
List of Subjects
amozie on DSK3GDR082PROD with PROPOSALS
47 CFR Part 1
Communications common carriers,
Equal employment opportunity,
Reporting and recordkeeping
requirements, Telecommunications,
Television.
47 CFR Part 32
Communications common carriers,
Reporting and recordkeeping
requirements, Telephone, Uniform
System of Accounts.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:48 May 16, 2018
47 CFR Part 51
§ 32.1
Communications common carriers,
Telecommunications.
The revised Uniform System of
Accounts (USOA) is a historical
financial accounting system which
reports the results of operational and
financial events in a manner which
enables both management and
regulators to assess these results within
a specified accounting period. The
USOA also provides the financial
community and others with financial
performance results. In order for an
accounting system to fulfill these
purposes, it must exhibit consistency
and stability in financial reporting
(including the results published for
regulatory purposes). Accordingly, the
USOA has been designed to reflect
stable, recurring financial data based to
the extent regulatory considerations
permit upon the consistency of the wellestablished body of accounting theories
and principles commonly referred to as
generally accepted accounting
principles (GAAP). The rules of this
part, and any other rules or orders that
are derivative of or dependent on these
Part 32 rules, do not apply to price cap
companies, and rate-of-return telephone
companies offering business data
services pursuant to § 61.50 of this
chapter, that have opted-out of USOA
requirements pursuant to the conditions
specified by the Commission in section
32.11(g).
■ 5. Section 32.11 is amended by
revising paragraph (g) to read as follows:
47 CFR Parts 61 and 69
Communications common carriers,
Reporting and recordkeeping
requirements, Telephone.
Federal Communications Commission.
Marlene Dortch,
Secretary.
Proposed Rules
For the reasons discussed in the
preamble, the Federal Communications
Commission proposes to amend 47 CFR
parts 1, 32, 51, 61 and 69 as follows:
PART 1—PRACTICE AND
PROCEDURE
XI. Ordering Clauses
Jkt 244001
22937
1. The authority citation for part 1 is
revised to read as follows:
■
Authority: 47 U.S.C. 151, 154(i), 154(j),
155, 157, 225, 227, 303(r), 309, 1403, 1404,
1451, and 1452.
2. Section 1.1409 is amended by
revising paragraph (g) to read as follows:
■
§ 1.1409 Commission consideration of the
complaint.
*
*
*
*
*
(g) A price cap company, or a rate-ofreturn carrier electing to provide service
pursuant to § 61.50 of this chapter, optsout of Part 32 may calculate attachment
rates for its poles, ducts, conduits, and
rights of way using either Part 32
accounting data or GAAP accounting
data. A company using GAAP
accounting data to compute rates to
attach to its poles, ducts, conduits, and
rights of way in any of the first twelve
years after opting-out must adjust
(increase or decrease) its annually
computed GAAP-based rates by an
Implementation Rate Difference for each
of the remaining years in the period.
The Implementation Rate Difference
means the difference between
attachment rates calculated by the
carrier under Part 32 and under GAAP
as of the last full year preceding the
carrier’s initial opting-out of Part 32
USOA accounting requirements.
PART 32—UNIFORM SYSTEM OF
ACCOUNTS FOR
TELECOMMUNICATIONS COMPANIES
3. The authority citation for part 32
continues to read as follows:
■
Authority: 47 U.S.C. 219, 220 as amended,
unless otherwise noted.
4. Section 32.1 is revised to read as
follows:
■
PO 00000
Frm 00055
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
Background
§ 32.11
Companies Subject to this part.
*
*
*
*
*
(g) Notwithstanding subsection (a), a
price cap company, or a rate-of-return
telephone company offering business
data services pursuant to § 61.50 of this
chapter, that elects to calculate its pole
attachment rates pursuant to section
1.1409(g) of this chapter will not be
subject to this Uniform System of
Accounts.
PART 51—INTERCONNECTION
6. The authority citation for part 51
continues to read as follows:
■
Authority: 47 U.S.C. 151–55, 201–05, 207–
09, 218, 220, 225–27, 251–54, 256, 271,
303(r), 332, 1302.
7. Section 51.903 is amended by
revising paragraph (g) to read:
■
§ 51.903
Definitions.
*
*
*
*
*
(g) Rate-of-Return Carrier is any
incumbent local exchange carrier not
subject to price cap regulation as that
term is defined in § 61.3(bb) of this
chapter, but only with respect to the
E:\FR\FM\17MYP1.SGM
17MYP1
22938
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 96 / Thursday, May 17, 2018 / Proposed Rules
territory in which it operates as an
incumbent local exchange carrier.
*
*
*
*
*
PART 61—TARIFFS
8. The authority citation for part 61
continues to read as follows:
■
Authority: Secs. 1, 4(i), 4(j), 201–05 and
403 of the Communications Act of 1934, as
amended; 47 U.S.C. 151, 154(i), 154(j), 201–
05 and 403, unless otherwise noted.
9. Section 61.41 is amended by
revising paragraph (d) and adding
paragraph (f) to read as follows:
■
§ 61.41
Price cap requirements generally.
*
*
*
*
*
(d) Except as provided in paragraph
(e) of this section, local exchange
carriers that become subject to price cap
regulation as that term is defined in
§ 61.3(ff) shall not be eligible to
withdraw from such regulation.
*
*
*
*
*
(f) Notwithstanding the requirements
of paragraphs (c) and (d) of this section,
a telephone company subject to rate-ofreturn regulation that is affiliated with
a price cap local exchange carrier may
provide business data services pursuant
to § 61.50 without converting other
services to price cap regulation.
■ 10. Section 61.50 is added to read as
follows:
amozie on DSK3GDR082PROD with PROPOSALS
§ 61.50 Incentive regulation of rate-ofreturn carrier provision of business data
services.
(a) A rate-of-return carrier, as defined
in § 51.903(g), has the option to offer
business data services to customers
pursuant to this section if the carrier
(1) Receives universal service
payments pursuant to the AlternativeConnect America Cost Model pursuant
to § 54.311;
(2) Is an affiliate of a price cap local
exchange carrier operating pursuant to a
waiver of § 61.41; or
(3) Receives universal service
payments pursuant to § 54.306.
(b) A rate-of-return carrier may not
elect to offer business data services to
customers pursuant to this section
unless it notifies the Chief of the
Wireline Competition Bureau at least
120 days before the effective date of the
election. Carriers may only elect this
option to be effective on July 1, [year].
(c) A rate-of-return carrier may elect
to offer business data services pursuant
to this section only if all affiliated rateof-return carriers make the election.
(d) A rate-of-return carrier electing to
offer business data services under this
section may continue to participate in
the NECA Traffic Sensitive Pool for
access services other than business data
services.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:48 May 16, 2018
Jkt 244001
(e) A rate-of-return carrier electing to
offer business data services pursuant to
this section shall employ the procedures
outlined in §§ 61.41 through .49 to
adjust its indexes to the extent those
sections are applicable to business data
services, except that:
(1) For the special access basket
specified in § 61.42(d)(5), the value of X
for local exchange carriers offering
service under this section shall be 2.0%
effective July 1, [year]; and
(2) Exogenous costs shall be allocated
to business data services based on
relative revenues, including any
universal service support amounts.
(f) Tariffs offering business data
services pursuant to this section may
offer those business data services at
different rates in different study areas.
(g) A rate-of-return carrier offering
business data services pursuant to this
section may make a low-end adjustment
pursuant to § 61.45(d)(1)(vii) of this
subpart unless it:
(1) Exercises the regulatory relief
pursuant to paragraph (j) of this section
in any part of its service region; or
(2) Exercises the option to use
Generally Accepted Accounting
Principles rather than the Part 32
Uniform System of Accounts pursuant
to § 32.11(g).
(h) Rate-of-return carriers electing to
offer business data services pursuant to
this section may offer transport and end
user channel terminations that include:
(1) Volume and term discounts;
(2) Contract-based tariffs, provided
that:
(i) Contract-based tariff services are
made generally available to all similarly
situated customers;
(ii) The rate-of-return carrier excludes
all contract-based tariff offerings from
incentive regulation pursuant to
§ 61.42(f) of this subpart;
(3) Ability to file tariff revisions on at
least one day’s notice, notwithstanding
the notice requirements for tariff filings
specified in § 61.58 of this chapter.
(j) A rate-of-return carrier electing to
offer business data services pursuant to
this section shall comply with the
requirements of section 69.805 of this
Chapter.
(k) The regulation of other services
offered by a rate-of-return carrier that
offers business data services pursuant to
this section shall not be modified as a
result of the requirements of this
section.
■ 11. Section 61.55 is amended by
revising paragraph (a) to read as follows:
§ 61.55
Contract-based tariffs.
Frm 00056
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
PART 69—ACCESS CHARGES
12. The authority citation for part 69
continues to read as follows:
■
Authority: 47 U.S.C. 154, 201, 202, 203,
205, 218, 220, 254, 403.
13. Section 69.114 is amended by
revising paragraph (a) to read as follows:
■
§ 69.114
Special Access.
(a) Appropriate subelements shall be
established for the use of equipment or
facilities that are assigned to the Special
Access element for purposes of
apportioning net investment, or that are
equivalent to such equipment or
facilities for companies subject to price
cap regulation as that term is defined in
§ 61.3(ff) of this chapter.
*
*
*
*
*
■ 14. Section 69.805 is amended by
revising paragraph (a) to read as follows:
§ 69.805 Prohibition on certain nondisclosure agreement conditions.
(a) In markets deemed noncompetitive, buyers and sellers of
business data services shall not enter
into a tariff, contract-based tariff, or
commercial agreement, including but
not limited to master service agreement,
that contains a non-disclosure
agreement as defined in § 69.801(h), that
restricts or prohibits disclosure of
information to the Commission, or
requires a prior request or legal
compulsion by the Commission to effect
such disclosure.
*
*
*
*
*
[FR Doc. 2018–10338 Filed 5–16–18; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6712–01–P
DEPARTMENT OF COMMERCE
National Oceanic and Atmospheric
Administration
50 CFR Part 622
[Docket No. 171031999–8428–01]
RIN 0648–BH39
Fisheries of the Caribbean, Gulf of
Mexico, and South Atlantic; SnapperGrouper Fishery of the South Atlantic
Region; Amendment 43
National Marine Fisheries
Service (NMFS), National Oceanic and
Atmospheric Administration (NOAA),
Commerce.
AGENCY:
(a) This section shall apply to price
cap local exchange carriers permitted to
offer contract-based tariffs under § 1.776
PO 00000
or § 69.805 of this chapter, as well as to
the offering of business data services by
rate-of-return carriers pursuant to
§ 61.50 of this part.
*
*
*
*
*
E:\FR\FM\17MYP1.SGM
17MYP1
Agencies
[Federal Register Volume 83, Number 96 (Thursday, May 17, 2018)]
[Proposed Rules]
[Pages 22923-22938]
From the Federal Register Online via the Government Publishing Office [www.gpo.gov]
[FR Doc No: 2018-10338]
=======================================================================
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION
47 CFR Parts 1, 32, 51, 61, and 69
[WC Docket No. 17-144; FCC 18-46]
Regulation of Business Data Services for Rate-of-Return Local
Exchange Carriers
AGENCY: Federal Communications Commission.
ACTION: Proposed rule.
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
SUMMARY: In this document, the Commission proposes to allow rate-of-
return carriers receiving universal service support under the
Alternative Connect America Cost Model (A-CAM) to voluntarily migrate
their lower speed circuit-based business data service (BDS) offerings
to incentive regulation. It also seeks comment on whether to remove ex
ante pricing regulation from these carriers' higher speed BDS offerings
and on whether further regulatory relief is warranted for these
carriers' lower-speed circuit-based BDS in areas deemed competitive by
a potential competitive market test. Additionally, the document
proposes to allow other rate-of-return carriers receiving fixed support
to opt into the same incentive regulation proposed for A-CAM carriers.
Finally, the Commission seeks comment on proposed rule changes that
would implement the proposals made in this document, including
corrections to inaccuracies contained in its current rules.
DATES: Comments are due on or before June 18, 2018; reply comments are
due on or before July 2, 2018. Parties that believe this document may
contain new or modified information collection requirements may submit
written Paperwork Reduction Act (PRA) comments to the Office of
Management and Budget (OMB), and other interested parties on or before
July 16, 2018.
ADDRESSES: You may submit comments, identified by WC Docket No. 17-144,
by any of the following methods:
Federal Communications Commission's Website: https://apps.fcc.gov/ecfs//. Follow the instructions for submitting comments.
People with Disabilities: Contact the FCC to request
reasonable accommodations (accessible format documents, sign language
interpreters, CART, etc.) by email: [email protected] or phone: 202-418-
0530 or TTY: 888-835-5322.
For detailed instructions for submitting comments and additional
information on the rulemaking process, see the SUPPLEMENTARY
INFORMATION section of this document.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: Justin Faulb, Wireline Competition
Bureau, Pricing Policy Division at 202-418-1589 or via email at
[email protected].
For additional information concerning any potential information
collection requirements contained in this document, send an email to
[email protected] or contact Nicole Ongele at [email protected].
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: This is a summary of the Commission's Notice
of Proposed Rulemaking (NPRM), WC Docket No. 17-144; FCC 18-46, adopted
on April 17, 2018 and released on April 18, 2018. The full-text of this
document may be found at the following internet address: https://apps.fcc.gov/edocs_public/attachmatch/FCC-18-46A1.doc.
Pursuant to Sec. Sec. 1.415 and 1.419 of the Commission's rules,
47 CFR 1.415, 1.419, interested parties may file comments and reply
comments on or before the dates indicated on the first page of this
document in Dockets WC 17-144. Comments may be filed using the
Commission's Electronic Comment Filing System (ECFS).
Electronic Filers: Comments may be filed electronically
using the internet by accessing the ECFS: https://apps.fcc.gov/ecfs/.
Paper Filers: Parties who choose to file by paper must
file an original and one copy of each filing. If more than one docket
or rulemaking number appears in the caption of this proceeding, filers
must submit two additional copies for each additional docket or
rulemaking number.
Filings can be sent by hand or messenger delivery, by commercial
overnight courier, or by first-class or overnight U.S. Postal Service
mail. All filings must be addressed to the Commission's Secretary:
Office of the Secretary, Federal Communications Commission.
All hand-delivered or messenger-delivered paper filings
for the Commission's Secretary must be delivered to FCC Headquarters at
445 12th St. SW, Room TW-A325, Washington, DC 20554. The filing hours
are 8:00 a.m. to 7:00 p.m. All hand deliveries must be held together
with rubber bands or fasteners. Any envelopes and boxes must be
disposed of before entering the building.
Commercial overnight mail (other than U.S. Postal Service
Express Mail and Priority Mail) must be sent to 9050 Junction Drive,
Annapolis Junction, MD 20701.
U.S. Postal Service first-class, Express, and Priority
mail must be
[[Page 22924]]
addressed to 445 12th Street SW, Washington, DC 20554.
People with Disabilities: To request materials in accessible
formats for people with disabilities (braille, large print, electronic
files, audio format), send an email to [email protected] or call the
Consumer & Governmental Affairs Bureau at 202-418-0530 (voice), 202-
418-0432 (TTY).
Synopsis
I. Introduction
1. The Commission has long recognized that, because it promotes
efficiency and reduces regulatory burdens, incentive regulation is
preferable to rate-of-return regulation. Therefore, in a series of
steps over the last three decades, the Commission provided incentives
to encourage incumbent local exchange carriers (LECs) to move from
rate-of-return regulation to incentive regulation. In this NPRM, we
take more steps along that path by proposing to allow rate-of-return
carriers that receive universal service support under the Alternative
Connect America Cost Model (A-CAM) to voluntarily migrate their lower
speed business data services (BDS) offerings to incentive regulation.
Because A-CAM carriers that elect to move away from rate-of-return
regulation for their BDS offerings (electing A-CAM carriers) will no
longer need to provide cost-based justification for their rates, we
propose to relieve them of burdensome cost-based pricing regulation,
including the obligation to conduct cost studies for purposes of
ratemaking. At the same time, because we recognize that ex ante pricing
regulation is of limited use--and often harmful--in a dynamic and
increasingly competitive market, we seek comment on identifying areas
served by electing A-CAM carriers that are sufficiently competitive
that their lower speed BDS offerings should be relieved of ex ante
pricing regulation, and we seek comment on whether to relieve electing
A-CAM carriers' higher speed BDS offerings from ex ante pricing
regulation. And, because there are other rate-of-return carriers that
receive model-based or fixed support, and would benefit from less
burdensome regulation, we propose to provide the same relief to those
carriers as we propose to provide to A-CAM carriers. Taken together we
expect these actions will spur entry, innovation, and competition in
the affected BDS markets.
II. Background
2. We start from the premise that incentive regulation encourages
carriers to be efficient by granting them at least a share of profits
obtained from cost reductions and allowing them to more aggressively
serve consumers (including by reducing prices) in the face of
competitive pressures. By contrast, rate-of-return regulation provides
incentives for firms to ``pad'' their rate base and to make
inefficiently high use of capital inputs. Additionally, rate-of-return
regulation requires carriers to account for the costs they incur in
providing service to justify their rates and universal service support
and thus unavoidably involves substantial regulatory burdens.
3. In 1990, the Commission began the process of shifting away from
cost-based regulation by adopting price cap rules that govern how the
largest incumbent LECs establish their interstate access charges. Price
cap regulation was intended to avoid the counterproductive incentives
of rate-of-return regulation in part by divorcing the annual rate
adjustments from the actual costs of each individual LEC, and in part
by adjusting the cap based on actual industry productivity experience.
In more recent years, a number of midsize carriers have voluntarily
converted from rate-of-return to price cap regulation.
4. In 2011, as part of comprehensive reform and modernization of
the universal service and intercarrier compensation systems, the
Commission adopted rate caps for switched access services for rate-of-
return carriers, thereby removing switched access services from rate-
of-return regulation. In 2016, the Commission gave rate-of-return
carriers the option of receiving forward looking model-based support
from the high-cost universal service support program, the A-CAM,
designed to estimate the cost of operating and maintaining an efficient
modern network. More than 200 carriers opted to receive A-CAM support
which eliminated the need for those carriers to conduct cost studies to
quantify the amount of high-cost support they receive. The Commission
observed that ``the election of model-based support places those
carriers in a different regulatory paradigm'' and that ``[e]ffectively,
the carriers that choose to take the voluntary path to the model are
electing incentive regulation for common line offerings.'' As a result,
rate-of-return carriers that elected the A-CAM support option are
currently subject to rate-of-return regulation and the attendant
requirement to conduct cost studies only for their BDS offerings.
5. In 2017, ITTA and USTelecom (together, Petitioners) filed a
joint petition requesting that the Commission allow A-CAM carriers and
other rate-of-return carriers that receive model-based support to opt
into the regulatory framework for BDS that the Commission recently
adopted for price cap carriers. The Petition explains that for such
carriers, ``continued compliance with rate-o[f]-return-based rate
regulation . . . entails significant costs.'' It further explains that
because carriers that receive universal service support based on a cost
model no longer have cost-based switched access charges, ``the need to
perform annual cost studies now applies only with respect to BDS.'' It
also claims that rate-of-return regulation deters investment in
networks and harms competition. The Wireline Competition Bureau
(Bureau) sought and received comment on the Petition. A number of
commenters support the Petition, arguing that cost savings and lighter
touch pricing regulation of model-based carriers' BDS would spur
competition, incentivize investment, benefit consumers, and eliminate
unnecessary administrative burdens. Other commenters expressed
concerns, including whether sufficient competition exists in A-CAM
study areas to justify reduced regulation.
6. In addition to facilitating rate-of-return carriers' move to
incentive regulation, the Commission has taken major steps to reduce
regulation for carriers that face competition. Given the inherent
inefficiencies of regulation, the Commission relies on competition to
the extent possible to ensure carriers' rates and practices are just
and reasonable. In 1999, the Commission granted pricing flexibility to
price cap carriers that provided service in areas where carriers could
demonstrate threshold levels of deployment by competitive providers.
The Pricing Flexibility Order adopted competitive triggers designed to
measure the extent to which competitors had made irreversible, sunk
investment in collocation and transport facilities. The Commission gave
price cap carriers that satisfied those triggers the flexibility to
offer BDS at unregulated rates through generally available and
individually negotiated tariffs. In addition, starting in 2007, upon
finding that competitive providers for BDS services existed in the
relevant price cap areas, the Commission granted a number of price cap
incumbent LECs forbearance from dominant carrier regulation, including
tariffing and price cap regulation, for their newer packet-based
broadband services. These forbearance orders concluded that a number of
competing providers exist for broadband BDS. They also concluded that
forbearance from burdensome regulations when competition exists
[[Page 22925]]
increases the amount of competition in the marketplace, ensuring that
rates and practices for services are just, reasonable, and not
unreasonably discriminatory.
7. The BDS Order the Commission adopted last year took another step
toward reducing regulation in response to the growth of competition. In
that order, the Commission found that reducing government intervention
and allowing market forces to continue working would further spur
entry, innovation, and competition in BDS markets served by price cap
carriers. The Commission applied ex ante rate regulation ``only where
competition is expected to materially fail to ensure just and
reasonable rates'' and stated its preference to rely ``on competition
rather than regulation, wherever purchasers can realistically turn to a
supplier beyond the incumbent LEC.'' Based on the record before it, the
Commission found that, on balance, competition was sufficient to ensure
just and reasonable rates for packet-based business data services, TDM
transport services, and higher bandwidth (i.e. above DS3) TDM services
(including OCn services) in areas served by price cap carriers. It also
adopted a competitive market test for TDM end user channel terminations
in price cap areas and refrained from ex ante pricing regulation of
those services in areas deemed competitive by that test.
III. Path Forward For Lower Speed Services
8. We seek comment on a regulatory framework that would provide
electing A-CAM carriers a path to allow a move from rate-of-return
regulation to a more efficient system of incentive regulation for their
TDM transport and end user channel terminations at speeds at or below a
DS3. In so doing, we propose to require that each A-CAM carrier's
decision about whether to move their BDS offerings out of rate-of-
return regulation be made on an all-or-nothing basis for all of an A-
CAM carrier's study areas that receive A-CAM support. We also invite
comment on what would be an appropriate market analysis for these lower
speed services and on a competitive market test that would allow us to
distinguish between markets that are sufficiently competitive so as not
to warrant the burdens of ex ante pricing regulation from those that
are not. Although the sections below focus on A-CAM carriers, because
we are proposing to allow other rate-of-return carriers that receive
model-based or other types of fixed support the opportunity to elect
the same or similar lighter-touch BDS regulation that we propose for A-
CAM carriers, we also seek comment on providing a path forward for
regulating such carriers' BDS offerings. As commenters respond to the
requests for comment below, we encourage discussion of how such a path
forward could work for other such rate-of-return carriers.
A. Incentive Regulation for Lower Capacity TDM Transport and End User
Channel Termination Services
9. We propose to allow electing A-CAM carriers to convert their
lower capacity TDM BDS offerings to an incentive regulatory approach
modelled on the rules the Commission adopted for price cap carriers'
lower speed BDS in noncompetitive areas, while still allowing such
carriers to be subject to the switched access rate transition and the
Eligible Recovery rules applicable to rate-of-return carriers. We
propose to allow conversion to incentive regulation for TDM transport
and end user channel termination services offered at speeds at or below
a DS3, as well as other generally lower speed non-packet-based services
that are commonly considered special access services. Are there other
special access offerings by rate-of-return carriers that we should
include in the incentive regulation option for A-CAM carriers? For
example, are there any telecommunications service components associated
with either residential digital subscriber line services or dedicated
internet access services that would qualify as special access services
that we should also allow to migrate to incentive regulation? We
anticipate that this approach will encourage competition for BDS in
areas served by electing A-CAM carriers and reduce unnecessary
regulatory burdens on electing A-CAM carriers. We seek comments on this
proposal, including on the benefits and costs of this approach.
10. The Commission has consistently acknowledged that incentive
regulation can foster appropriate incentives for carriers to be
efficient and to innovate. Under price cap regulation, as opposed to
cost-based regulation, carriers have the incentive to become more
efficient, to reduce costs, and to innovate as a means of increasing
their profits. Moreover, an appropriate X-factor and periodic review by
the Commission can ensure that carriers share some or all of these
efficiencies with their customers. We invite parties to identify with
specificity any short-comings in the proposal and to suggest
alternatives that could achieve the objectives more efficiently. Given
the well-recognized benefits of incentive regulation, we also seek
comment on whether we should make this election mandatory for all A-CAM
carriers.
1. Relieving Electing A-CAM Carriers of Rate-of-Return Regulation for
Their Lower Speed TDM BDS Offerings
11. We propose to relieve electing A-CAM carriers of a variety of
regulatory obligations that pertain to rate-of-return regulation,
including the obligation to perform cost studies. Rate-of-return
carriers are required by our rules to perform relatively burdensome
cost studies to support their rate development. Petitioners and other
commenters identify elimination of cost studies as a primary benefit of
allowing A-CAM carriers to elect incentive regulation. We invite
parties to quantify the burdens of preparing cost studies (including
costs and/or hours of labor) and comment on whether cost studies impose
any special burdens on smaller carriers. We also seek comment on
whether data from A-CAM carriers' cost studies are necessary in the
performance of any Commission regulatory function. If so, will the
benefits of the data collected from electing A-CAM carriers' cost
studies outweigh the burden of requiring them to continue to provide
that data when they are no longer offering cost-based services? Are
there other, less burdensome ways of collecting the relevant data from
electing A-CAM carriers that we should explore? Are there other issues
we need to address before relieving A-CAM carriers of the burden of
cost studies? If so, how shall we address them?
12. We also propose to allow electing A-CAM carriers pricing
flexibility for their lower capacity TDM services similar to that
granted by the Commission in the BDS Order to price cap carriers in
their provision of lower capacity TDM services in counties deemed
noncompetitive by the competitive market test we adopted for price cap
carriers. We propose to allow electing A-CAM carriers to offer term and
volume discounts and contract-based services for their TDM transport
and end user channel termination services offered at speeds at or below
a DS3. Electing A-CAM carriers would be required to maintain generally
available tariffed rates subject to incentive regulation for these
lower speed TDM transport and end user channel terminations, and other
special access services included in their tariffs. We seek comment on
these proposals.
13. We also propose to allow electing A-CAM carriers to remain in
the NECA traffic-sensitive tariff for switched access services, and to
continue to be subject to the switched access rate cap provisions of
section 51.909 and the
[[Page 22926]]
Eligible Recovery rules in section 51.917 of the Commission's rules. We
propose to require electing A-CAM carriers to remove their special
access services from the NECA traffic-sensitive tariff. We seek comment
on these proposals.
14. We recognize that our proposed approach for electing A-CAM
carriers treats TDM transport differently than the BDS Order does for
price cap carriers. While the Commission found TDM transport to be
competitive in price cap areas generally, here we propose to allow
electing A-CAM carriers to convert lower speed TDM transport services
to incentive regulation but not to immediately eliminate ex ante
pricing regulation for them. We propose this different approach given
that competition for such services may not be as robust in the less
dense, more rural areas that A-CAM carriers typically serve. We seek
comment on this aspect of our proposal, and on what data exist to
confirm or invalidate our assumption. The Commission observed in the
BDS Order that competitive transport services are typically deployed at
locations where sufficient demand is aggregated to enable a competitor
to justify investment. To what extent is there sufficient aggregated
demand in A-CAM areas to justify the deployment of competitive
transport? Are there instances where demand for TDM transport services
may be increasing, creating the precondition for competitive entry in
the future? Alternatively, has the overall decline in demand for TDM
services also affected the demand for lower speed TDM transport
services in A-CAM areas? Finally, we seek comment on allowing
additional regulatory relief for A-CAM carriers' TDM transport offered
at speeds at or below a DS3 in areas deemed competitive by a
competitive market test we seek comment on below.
15. We do not propose to transition electing A-CAM carriers to
incentive regulation for switched access services. The transition
provisions for switched access rates and Eligible Recovery rules for
rate-of-return carriers adopted by the USF/ICC Transformation Order are
well established, have been upheld on appeal, and have been partially
implemented; disrupting these transitions would likely impose
additional costs and increase uncertainty, deterring investment and
deployment. We also seek comment on the benefits and costs of our
proposed approach. The Petition sought an ``exception'' to Sec. 61.41
of the Commission's rules (the so-called ``all or nothing'' rule),
which requires all of a price cap carrier's study areas and rates,
including those of affiliates and carriers it purchases or merges with,
to be subject to price cap regulation. We propose to amend Sec. 61.41
to create an exception for the alternative regulatory structure we
propose in this NPRM, and we seek comment on this proposal. Are there
any other rules we should consider waiving or amending in the context
of this proceeding?
2. Implementing Optional Incentive Regulation for Lower Capacity TDM
Services
16. In this section, we make specific proposals regarding the terms
of the incentive regulation we propose to adopt for electing A-CAM
carriers and seek comment on these proposals.
a. Election
17. We propose to require carriers that elect to move off rate-of-
return regulation for their BDS services to move to incentive
regulation at the holding company level for study areas in all states
that elected to receive A-CAM support rather than electing on an
individual carrier or study area basis, as proposed by Petitioners.
Requiring election at the holding company level will ensure cost
savings from the elimination of annual cost studies to be realized by
all affiliated carriers electing A-CAM support. Carriers have already
had the opportunity to elect between A-CAM and cost-based support at a
state-wide level. Allowing A-CAM carriers to elect regulatory treatment
at a more disaggregated level would appear to be inconsistent with the
underlying premise of price caps, which assumed a broad representation
of carrier operations to provide a basis for establishing an industry-
wide productivity factor. Currently, there are 262 A-CAM companies when
calculated at the state level and 207 when calculated at the holding
company level. We invite parties to comment on the proposed level of
election. Parties believing the proposed holding company level is too
high should explain why a more disaggregated level would be in the
public interest. Any explanation should include concrete examples of
why the proposed level would preclude a significant number of A-CAM
carriers from electing incentive regulation. Parties should address
whether other aspects of the proposal could be modified to make the
proposed level of election more acceptable.
18. We propose to make incentive regulation for electing A-CAM
carriers effective on the July 1st following adoption of an order in
this proceeding, which is the deadline for the annual access tariff
filing. Using July 1st will simplify the tariffing process for
implementing any change and is consistent with the price cap rules' use
of the prior calendar-year demand data for their price cap
calculations. We invite parties to comment on this proposal, and to
suggest other timing options that may work, identifying the benefits
and drawbacks of such proposals. The proposals should address the
periods for determining cost and demand for electing A-CAM carriers. We
also invite parties to comment on whether we should allow a one-time
opportunity to elect, or whether additional election opportunities
should be allowed. If more than one opportunity to elect is offered,
what should the timing be for any additional election opportunities?
19. We have recently proposed making a second A-CAM offer. In the
event that additional rate-of-return carriers become A-CAM carriers, we
propose that they may elect to adopt incentive regulation at the next
annual tariff filing date that follows their election. We also propose
to allow the new electing A-CAM carriers to adopt the other lighter
touch regulatory options that are available to electing A-CAM carriers
at that time. We invite parties to comment on these proposals.
b. Initial Rate Levels
20. We propose to allow electing A-CAM carriers that currently file
their own tariffed rates for BDS offerings to use their existing rates
to set their initial BDS rates under incentive regulation. The
Commission used this method when allowing rate-of-return carriers
filing their own rates to convert to price cap regulation. The demand
to be used for the incentive regulation calculations would be that of
the previous calendar year. The carrier would then apply the prescribed
X-factor and the inflation factor, two variables in the Commission's
existing formula for the price cap index (PCI), which would result in
the proposed rates in the first year of incentive regulation, and each
year thereafter. We invite parties to comment on this proposal. We ask
that any party disagreeing with this approach submit a detailed
proposal for setting initial rates, including an explanation of why its
preferred approach would be equal to or better than the approach we
propose.
21. Establishing initial BDS rates for electing A-CAM carriers
participating in the NECA traffic-sensitive pool is more complicated
because they are charging a pooled rate, which does not reflect the
actual costs of the pooling carrier. The NECA pool BDS rates are
[[Page 22927]]
therefore not the proper rates to use as initial BDS rates. We
therefore propose that each electing A-CAM carrier in the pool
establish its initial BDS rates by multiplying the NECA pool rate the
carrier has been charging by a net contribution/recipient factor. Thus,
an A-CAM carrier with more BDS revenues than the BDS settlements it
receives from the pool would have its pool rate reduced commensurately.
The opposite would occur for an electing A-CAM carrier that received
more BDS settlements than the BDS revenues it produced. The carrier
would then apply the prescribed X-factor and the inflation factor,
which would result in the proposed rates in the first year of incentive
regulation, and each year thereafter. This approach avoids the
necessity of doing new cost studies for each study area of the electing
A-CAM carriers. We invite parties to comment on this approach.
Alternatively, commenters may suggest other approaches, such as doing
cost studies for the preceding calendar year, or other twelve-month
period. Parties making such alternative proposals should address the
manner in which the alternative time period data would be incorporated
into the incentive regulation calculations.
22. Are there other approaches we should take in determining how
electing A-CAM carriers should establish initial BDS rates? Are there
other adjustments that we should make to our proposed initial rate
setting process? For example, should the initial rates be lower than
current rates because of the cost savings electing carriers will
realize by moving to incentive regulation? If so, how much should be
shared with consumers and how should such amount be determined? In a
2012 waiver petition seeking to move from rate-of-return to price cap
status, FairPoint Communications, Inc., proposed reducing its special
access rates by a percentage of the anticipated cost savings. We invite
parties to comment on these issues and to suggest how such amounts
should be determined, especially if another cost study is to be
avoided.
c. Special Access Basket, Categories and Subcategories
23. Consistent with the BDS Order, we propose to retain the special
access basket, categories and subcategories, and the attendant rules
governing the allowed annual adjustments. We propose to require each
electing A-CAM carrier to initialize its PCI for the special access
basket and associated service band indices (SBIs) at 100 and to use the
rate adjustment rules for price cap carriers contained in sections
61.45-48 of our rules, as appropriate, to reflect the prescribed
productivity factor, the inflation factor, and any required exogenous
cost adjustment in the PCI, to ensure that the Actual Price Index (API)
does not exceed the PCI, and that the SBIs for each category or
subcategory do not exceed their upper limits. The category and sub-
category requirements are designed to limit the degree to which a
carrier can raise rates in any given year in an effort to avoid anti-
competitive pricing. We invite parties to comment on this proposal. Are
there other approaches we should take? Are there other categories or
sub-categories needed for A-CAM carriers that were not necessary for
price cap carriers? We request that parties recommending that we modify
the categories or sub-categories explain why such a change would
improve the functioning of the incentive regulation plan and/or the BDS
market and produce benefits for consumers.
d. Productivity Factor and Measure of Inflation
24. Consistent with the BDS Order, we also propose to adopt an X-
factor of two percent to reflect the productivity growth that electing
A-CAM carriers are likely to experience in the provision of these
services relative to productivity growth in the overall economy in the
foreseeable future and to use Gross Domestic Product-Price Index (GDP-
PI) as the measure of inflation that electing A-CAM carriers will use
in their PCI calculations. We do not propose to incorporate a consumer
productivity dividend (CPD) adjustment into this X-factor. Based on the
industry-wide analysis provided in the BDS Order and Petitioners'
proposal that we use a two percent X-Factor, we believe an X-factor of
two percent will ensure just and reasonable rates for BDS offered by
electing A-CAM carriers, and that use of the GDP-PI is appropriate. We
seek comment on this proposal.
25. Are there reasons we should use a different productivity factor
for electing A-CAM providers than we use for price cap carriers? We
request that any party proposing a different productivity factor or
measure of inflation factor describe with specificity how their
proposed X-Factor is derived and why it would be a better forecast of
the expected pattern of growth than what we propose herein.
26. We also seek comment on the extent to which the voluntary
nature of the election interacts with the appropriate level of the X-
Factor. For example, are there relationships between different factors
that could warrant that the Commission increase or decrease the X-
Factor? Should the level of the X-Factor be affected by whether the
carrier election is for all A-CAM study areas, or made on a more
disaggregated level?
e. Exogenous Costs
27. We seek comment on the treatment that should be accorded
exogenous costs if we allow A-CAM carriers to elect to move to
incentive regulation. Exogenous costs are those costs that are beyond
the control of the carrier, as determined by the Commission. Section
61.45(d) of our rules provides for an exogenous cost adjustment for
price cap carriers to be apportioned on a cost-causative basis between
price cap services as a group, and excluded services as a group.
Exogenous cost changes attributed to price cap services are recovered
from services other than those used to calculate the average traffic-
sensitive charge. A-CAM carriers have been removed from rate-of-return
regulation for universal service purposes and for interstate access
services other than BDS. We invite parties to address how the principle
of cost causation should be applied in determining the amount of any
exogenous costs to be assigned to the BDS basket for electing A-CAM
carriers. We propose that exogenous costs be allocated based on a ratio
of BDS revenues to total revenues from all regulated services and A-CAM
universal service support payments. We invite parties to address
whether some other basis would be preferable, including the rationale
for the alternative approach.
f. Low-End Adjustment
28. Consistent with the BDS Order, we propose to adopt a low-end
adjustment mechanism to provide an appropriate backstop to ensure that
electing A-CAM carriers are not subject to protracted periods of low
earnings. Failure to include any adjustment for such circumstances
could harm customers as well as shareholders of such a carrier as a
below-normal rate-of-return over a prolonged period could threaten the
carrier's ability to raise the capital necessary to provide modern,
efficient services to customers. The low-end adjustment mechanism would
permit a one-time adjustment to a single year's BDS rates to avoid
back-to-back annual earnings below a set benchmark. If an electing A-
CAM carrier's BDS earnings fall below the low-end adjustment mark in a
base year period, it would be entitled to adjust its rates upward to
target earnings to the benchmark. We propose that, consistent with past
[[Page 22928]]
practice, the low-end adjustment benchmark should be set 100 basis
points below the authorized rate of return for rate-of-return carriers.
We propose that electing A-CAM carriers that exercise downward pricing
flexibility (for example, by entering into a contract tariff with a
customer), or elect the option to use generally accepted accounting
practices (GAAP) rather than the Part 32 Uniform System of Accounts as
set forth in our recent Part 32 Accounting Order, will be ineligible
for a low-end adjustment.
29. We invite interested parties to comment on the proposal to
adopt a low-end adjustment mechanism. We ask parties to comment on
whether this measure will ensure that electing A-CAM carriers have the
opportunity to attract sufficient capital. We note that an A-CAM
carrier would have to present cost data to support a claim for a low-
end adjustment. Because eliminating the need for cost studies is one of
the driving objectives behind Petitioners' proposal, we ask parties to
comment on whether there are alternative ways to make the required
determinations short of performing a full cost study. Parties offering
suggestions should explain the proposed mechanism in sufficient detail
that a comparison to the results of a cost study can be made. We also
seek comment on the appropriateness of setting the benchmark for the
low-end adjustment at 100 basis points below the authorized rate of
return for rate-of-return carriers. We note that this proposal would
allow the benchmark to track the gradual reduction in the authorized
rate-of-return as it transitions down.
g. Cost Assignment and Jurisdictional Separations Rules
30. Pursuant to section 10 of the Act, and to implement our new
incentive regulation for those A-CAM carriers that elect incentive
regulation, we propose to forbear from application of our cost
assignment rules, including jurisdictional separations requirements.
Consistent with our previous forbearance orders for price cap carriers,
we propose to define cost assignment rules to include the rules
governing the assignment of costs and revenues by carriers. We seek
comment on our proposed definition.
31. In providing similar forbearance to price cap carriers, the
Commission observed that such rules ``were developed when the ILECs'
interstate rates and many of their intrastate rates were set under
rate-based, cost-of-service regulation. The Commission has explained
that `because price cap regulation severs the direct link between
regulated costs and prices, a carrier is not able automatically to
recoup misallocated non-regulated costs by raising basic service
rates,' thus reducing incentives to shift non-regulated costs to
regulated services.'' Does the same reasoning for forbearance apply to
A-CAM carriers electing incentive regulation? Will the operation of the
incentive regulation rules we propose make enforcement of the cost
assignment and separations rules unnecessary to ensure just, reasonable
and not unjustly or unreasonably discriminatory charges, practices,
classifications, and regulations, or make enforcement of those rules
unnecessary to protect consumers from unjust, unreasonable, and
unjustly or unreasonably discriminatory rates, practices,
classifications, and regulations? Is enforcement of such regulations
unnecessary to protect consumers? Would forbearance be consistent with
the public interest and would the reduction of regulatory burdens
improve market competitiveness?
32. We further propose to condition any grant of forbearance from
application of the cost assignment and jurisdictional separations rules
for an electing A-CAM carrier that froze their separations category
relationships on its conducting a cost study for the preceding calendar
year. The A-CAM carrier would then adjust the initialized BDS rates
determined pursuant to the procedures described above by the results of
the cost study. We invite parties to comment on this proposal and to
identify any constraints that should be placed on application of the
cost study results to the development of revised access charges,
including BDS rates. For example, should a carrier be limited in the
extent it may adjust the relative price relationships between business
data services that may be established?
33. Above, we propose procedures for electing A-CAM carriers to use
in establishing initial BDS rates under incentive regulation that
assume other factors remained unchanged. Forbearing from cost
allocation and jurisdictional separations requirements for A-CAM
carriers electing incentive regulation, however, would change one of
the controlled factors. We invite comment on what adjustments, if any,
we should allow an A-CAM carrier that elects to freeze its category
relationships to make to its rates to ensure that its BDS rates are
just and reasonable pursuant to section 201 of the Act.
h. GAAP Accounting
34. We propose to allow electing A-CAM carriers to use GAAP for
keeping their accounts, should they choose to do so. The Commission
recently revised the Part 32 rules to allow price cap LECs to elect to
use GAAP in recording and reporting their financial data, subject to
two targeted accounting requirements. Electing carriers may either (a)
calculate an Implementation Rate Difference between the attachment
rates calculated by the price cap carrier under the Uniform System of
Accounts (USOA) and under GAAP as of the last full year preceding the
carrier's initial opting-out of Part 32 USOA accounting requirements;
or (b) comply with GAAP accounting for all purposes other than those
associated with setting pole attachment rates while continuing to use
the Part 32 accounts and procedures necessary to establish and evaluate
pole attachment rates. Electing carriers must adjust their annually
computed GAAP-based rates by the Implementation Rate Difference for a
period of 12 years after the election. This frees price cap carriers
from having to maintain two sets of books: One for financial reporting
purposes consistent with GAAP and one for regulatory reporting purposes
consistent with the accounting requirements of Part 32. For the same
reasons, we propose to allow electing A-CAM carriers to have the option
to use GAAP. We propose to require electing A-CAM carriers that choose
to use GAAP accounting to be subject to the same data provisioning
requirements as price cap carriers, including the requirements relating
to the calculation of pole attachment rates. As a result, such carriers
will have to determine an Implementation Rate Difference to apply in
calculating their pole attachment rates. We seek comment on this
proposal. Are there other issues with allowing electing A-CAM carriers
to use GAAP accounting that we should consider?
B. Providing a Path To Relieve Electing A-CAM Carriers of Ex Ante
Pricing Regulation for Lower Speed End User Channel Terminations and
TDM Transport in Competitive Areas
35. We seek comment on whether we should adopt a competitive market
test (CMT) to assess the availability of actual and likely competitive
options in the provision of transport and last-mile services in areas
served by electing A-CAM carriers and to remove from ex ante pricing
regulation DS1 and DS3 end user channel terminations, TDM transport at
speeds at or below a DS3, and other generally lower speed BDS
[[Page 22929]]
provided (or some subset of these services) by electing A-CAM carriers
in areas that the CMT finds competitive. If so, what should be the
elements of such a test and what are the costs and benefits of adopting
such a test? We also seek comment on whether we should use different
metrics and/or different tests to measure the competitiveness of lower
speed end user channel terminations as compared to lower speed TDM
transport services.
36. If we adopt a CMT for electing A-CAM carriers, should we use
the CMT the Commission adopted in the BDS Order for price cap carriers
(the existing CMT) as a starting point? The existing CMT features two
prongs, based on data from price cap study areas. The first measures
whether 50 percent of the locations with BDS demand in a county are
within a half-mile of a location that was served by a competitive
provider, based on the 2015 Collection. The second uses Form 477 data
to measure whether a cable operator offers a minimum of 10/1 Mbps
broadband service in 75 percent of the census blocks in the county. If
either prong is satisfied, that county is deemed competitive for price
cap carriers' BDS. Below, we seek comment on several options for a CMT
for electing A-CAM carriers, some of which include the use of the
existing CMT. Beside the options we offer below, are there other
options we should consider if we choose to adopt a CMT? What are the
costs and benefits of each?
1. CMT Options
a. Rerun the Second Prong of the Existing CMT Using 477 Data for A-CAM
Areas
37. First, we seek comment on adopting a CMT that uses only a
version of the second prong of the existing CMT using data from areas
served by A-CAM carriers. Under this approach, we would rerun the
second prong of the existing CMT using FCC Form 477 data only from
electing A-CAM carriers' study areas. We would then deem competitive,
for purposes of relieving electing A-CAM carriers' lower speed TDM BDS
services from ex ante pricing regulation, any county where a cable
operator or other competitive provider offers a minimum of 10/1 Mbps
broadband service in 75 percent of the census blocks in the portion of
the county served by an electing A-CAM carrier. This approach has the
benefit of simplicity. It would allow us to use FCC Form 477 data that
we regularly collect and would identify areas served by electing A-CAM
carriers that competitors or potential competitors already serve.
Because we would not be using the first prong of the existing CMT,
there would be no need to conduct a BDS data collection for A-CAM
carriers akin to the 2015 Collection. For a variety of reasons, we are
not inclined to adopt an approach that would require another such
large-scale data collection. The burdens associated with such a data
collection would be substantial for A-CAM carriers and other providers
of data, and could significantly delay Commission action without
corresponding benefits. However, we invite comment on this issue.
Because of the lack of cable service in many rate-of-return study
areas, we recognize that this test will likely result in very few A-CAM
counties being deemed competitive. Does that suggest this test is
accurate in identifying competition in A-CAM areas? Are there other
costs and benefits to this approach that we should consider?
b. Use the Results of the Existing CMT
38. Petitioners propose that we apply the existing CMT to electing
A-CAM carriers' BDS offerings. Under this proposal, an electing A-CAM
carrier's lower speed TDM BDS offerings would be relieved of ex ante
pricing regulation in those counties that have already been deemed
competitive by the existing CMT. Petitioners recognize that there are
78 purely rate-of-return counties that were not analyzed by the
existing CMT. They propose to use the second prong of the existing CMT
to determine whether those counties should be considered competitive.
Petitioners argue that this approach would involve minimal
administrative and compliance burdens and would avoid the need for
revising and re-running the CMT for electing A-CAM carriers or
analyzing any additional data.
39. We seek comment on Petitioners' proposed approach. The existing
CMT was developed for price cap carriers' service areas and involved
analysis of competition only in price cap areas. The Commission did not
consider competition in A-CAM markets. Is an analysis of existing or
potential competition in price cap areas of a county an appropriate way
to determine whether competition or potential competition exists in
areas of that county served by an electing A-CAM carrier? Is it likely
to result in deregulating lower speed TDM-based BDS services offered by
electing A-CAM carriers in counties where such carriers will not face
competitive pressure in pricing those services? Are there other
benefits or drawbacks to this approach that we should consider?
c. Apply a Modified Two-Prong CMT to Areas Served by Electing A-CAM
Carriers
40. Another option would be to adopt a CMT for electing A-CAM
carriers using prongs similar to those of the existing CMT, but using
data specific to areas served by electing A-CAM carriers. We seek
comment on this approach. We recognize that for purposes of the first
prong of the new CMT, this approach would require a data collection
sufficient to allow us to identify for each county served by an
electing A-CAM carrier whether 50 percent of the locations with BDS
demand in that part of the county are within a half-mile of a location
that was served by a competitive provider. Such a collection could be
limited to electing A-CAM carriers and their competitors. Nonetheless,
we have reservations about the relative costs and benefits of
conducting such a data collection. And, the current record is split on
whether we should consider a new data collection. We seek comment on
how to most efficiently collect relevant data and on whether the
burdens of such a data collection outweigh the benefits. We also seek
comment on other benefits and drawbacks to this option.
d. Adopt a CMT Based on a Market Analysis Specific to Areas Served by
A-CAM Carriers
41. A fourth option is to create a whole new CMT based on a
competitive market analysis specific to BDS services in areas served by
electing A-CAM carriers. Petitioners argue that the BDS market analysis
conducted in the BDS Order with respect to price cap areas applies
equally to rate-of-return areas served by A-CAM carriers. We seek
comment on Petitioners' argument.
42. In the BDS Order, the Commission conducted a broad, data-
driven, multi-faceted market analysis based on a comprehensive data
collection to evaluate the extent of competition for BDS in price cap
areas. The Commission's market analysis was informed by, but not
limited to, traditional antitrust principles, such as the market power
analysis performed by U.S. antitrust agencies. The Commission analyzed
the product market, geographic market, barriers to entry, and other
characteristics of price cap BDS markets.
43. If we conduct a new market analysis, should it be similar to
the market analysis conducted by the Commission in the BDS Order as a
precondition to determining whether competition is sufficient to
warrant lighter touch regulation in certain BDS
[[Page 22930]]
markets? If we do conduct a new market analysis, we propose to consider
product and geographic markets, competitive entry, and other market
attributes to ascertain the extent to which nearby potential BDS
competitors are likely to temper price, resulting in reasonably
competitive prices over the short- to medium-term (i.e., up to three to
five years). Would this be the right approach to assessing the level of
competition for BDS in A-CAM areas? What other approaches should we
consider taking? How should we analyze transport under our market
analysis? Would a competitive market analysis give us sufficient basis
to go beyond the incremental deregulation of lower speed transport that
we propose above? We ask commenters to support their positions with
data that would help us determine whether markets are sufficiently
competitive to warrant deregulatory treatment.
44. Data for a Market Analysis. If we conduct a market analysis,
what relevant data are available and what are the potential utility and
limitations of the available data? Should we review FCC Form 477 data
on mass market broadband service to determine the extent to which they
serve as evidence of the presence of network facilities capable of
delivering reasonably competitive BDS over the short- to medium-term
(three to five years) in A-CAM areas? We seek comment on the data,
methodologies, and modeling used to develop the A-CAM study area
boundaries, including state-level location density data, the A-CAM
model, and geocoded location data submitted to USAC and the extent they
can assist us in analyzing the BDS market in A-CAM areas.
45. To the extent the Commission's existing data sources are
insufficient, we seek data from commenters on facilities-based BDS
providers serving A-CAM areas that would help us to ascertain markets
with reasonably competitive conditions to justify lighter touch
regulatory treatment. Are there existing data similar to data collected
as part of the 2015 Collection that would help us better understand or
estimate the location of BDS demand in A-CAM areas, including consumers
and business locations served (or readily served) by BDS, as well as
data on market structure, demand, pricing, and competitive pressures in
those areas? Does similar data exist that could identify BDS demand for
transport in A-CAM areas? If we have to collect new data, what data
should we collect and what is the most efficient way to collect it?
Does the cost of conducting and analyzing such a data collection
outweigh the benefits of conducting an A-CAM specific market analysis?
46. Product Market. If we conduct a new market analysis, should we
use the same analysis to define the product market for lower speed TDM
end user channel terminations and transport in A-CAM areas as we used
to define the product market for BDS in price cap areas in the BDS
Order? We anticipate that the product market for BDS in A-CAM areas
will closely resemble the BDS product market delineated in the BDS
Order for price cap areas and seek comment on this belief and on
potential differences that may exist between the two types of markets.
Despite these similarities, we recognize that there may be differences
between price cap areas and A-CAM areas that may affect the BDS product
markets in these areas. Are there products that were marketed or
supplied to BDS customers in price cap areas that are not in demand,
marketed, or otherwise supplied in A-CAM areas as a BDS substitute, and
to what extent do products that are not in the same BDS product market
nonetheless exert competitive pressure on prices for BDS in A-CAM
areas?
47. Geographic Market. In the BDS Order, the Commission defined the
geographic market in terms of ``the area to which consumers can
`practically turn for alternative sources,' and within which providers
can reasonably compete.'' Consistent with the BDS Order, should we
define the geographic market as an area where customers have medium-
term competitive choices for BDS based on customer locations within a
half mile of a location served over the facilities of at least one non-
incumbent competitive provider? We encourage commenters to provide data
and analysis to support their positions.
48. Competitive Entry. As part of our analysis, and consistent with
the BDS Order, should we consider how varying market characteristics
impact entry by non-incumbent competing BDS providers in A-CAM areas,
along with evidence of entry barriers being overcome by traditional and
non-traditional competing providers? We seek comment on identifiable
market features in A-CAM areas, including carrier market share, number
and size distribution of competing firms, the nature of competitors'
barriers to entry, the availability of reasonably substitutable
services, the level of demand elasticity, and whether a firm controls
bottleneck facilities to help us identify where competition is
sufficient to make imposing the burdens of ex ante pricing regulation
unnecessary and counterproductive.
49. We seek comment on the number, type, size, concentration, and
market share of nearby BDS competitors (i.e., within a half-mile) that
operate in A-CAM study areas, in the form of facilities-based wired
communications network providers, that temper prices to reasonably
competitive levels in the short- to medium-term.
50. Consistent with the BDS Order, should we consider as part of
our market analysis the extent to which providers and potential
providers face barriers to enter the BDS marketplace in A-CAM areas? We
seek comment on the timeliness, likelihood, and sufficiency of a
competitor's entry into the BDS market in A-CAM areas. We seek comment
on the barriers facing carriers for both lower speed TDM end user
channel terminations and transport. How are the markets different? For
example, in the BDS Order, the Commission found lower entry barriers
for deploying TDM transport services than for end user channel
termination services. Is this accurate for A-CAM carrier study areas as
well? Would buildout and entry by an entrant be rapid enough to render
incumbent LECs' attempts to set prices above competitive levels
unprofitable? Would such entry occur over a longer timeframe, such as
three to five years, and, if so, would that justify taking the same
light touch regulatory approach here as taken in the BDS Order? To what
extent is market entry profitable (and thus likely) based on projected
expenditures and revenues from customers and potential customers? Is
the presence of a second provider in the relevant geographic market,
whether a non-incumbent LEC or a cable operator, sufficient to
constrain prices to competitive levels? To what extent does the half-
mile test that was derived from the market analysis of price cap areas
relate to demand densities in those areas that may not be present in A-
CAM areas? Finally, we seek comment on the extent incumbents and non-
incumbent entrants, particularly cable companies, are upgrading or
building out their networks to sources of BDS demand in A-CAM study
areas.
2. Updating CMT Results for A-CAM Carriers
51. The BDS Order directed the Bureau to review the existing price
cap CMT every three years using the second prong of the test based on
Form 477 data. If we adopt a CMT for electing A-CAM carriers, we seek
comment on whether we should conduct similar periodic reviews of any
CMT we adopt for such carriers. For administrative ease, should we
target the timing of our
[[Page 22931]]
initial review of the results of a CMT for electing A-CAM carriers to
coincide with our initial review of price cap served areas? Under the
BDS Order, counties that were determined to be competitive were no
longer subject to review of their status in subsequent updates of the
CMT. Should we treat A-CAM areas similarly? If not, we seek comment on
alternatives to grandfathering those A-CAM areas.
3. Regulation in Areas Deemed Competitive by the CMT
52. If we adopt a CMT for areas served by electing A-CAM carriers,
consistent with the BDS Order, we propose to refrain from ex ante
pricing regulation for lower speed transport and TDM end-user channel
terminations in areas deemed competitive. We also seek comment on
whether forbearing from section 203 tariffing requirements for these
services in these areas would meet the statutory criteria of section 10
of the Act. As we did in the BDS Order, we recognize the continuing
applicability and importance of sections 201, 202, and 208 of the Act
to ensure that consumers will remain protected from unjust and
unreasonable rates in areas deemed competitive. We seek comment on this
proposal.
IV. Removing Ex Ante Pricing Regulation From Packet-Based BDS and TDM-
Based BDS Providing Bandwidth in Excess of a DS3
53. We also seek comment on whether we should eliminate ex ante
pricing regulation of packet-based and TDM-based business data services
providing bandwidth in excess of a DS3 offered by those carriers that
elect to move their lower speed BDS offerings from rate-of-return
regulation to incentive regulation. If so, should we provide 36 months
for such a transition? If we transition these high-speed services,
consistent with the BDS Order, we would continue to recognize the
applicability and importance of sections 201, 202, and 208 of the Act
in protecting consumers from unjust and unreasonable practices.
54. With respect to price cap areas, the Commission's market
analysis did ``not show compelling evidence of market power'' in
incumbent LECs' provision of packet-based services and higher capacity
TDM-based business data services (in excess of the bandwidth of a DS3),
particularly for higher bandwidth services. We seek comment on whether
these observations offer any insights on the nature and extent of
competition in A-CAM areas. Are markets for higher capacity TDM-based
BDS offerings (above the bandwidth of a DS3) and packet-based services
likely to be sufficiently competitive in A-CAM areas over the next
three to five years such that the harms of price regulation in these
markets, most notably in terms of discouraging the extension of
competition, are likely to be greater than any harms that may occur
were we not to regulate? Are these markets sufficiently competitive to
outweigh any benefits of ex ante pricing regulation? Parties are
encouraged to provide evidence to support their arguments. We seek
comment on the extent to which Commission or other data could
facilitate our evaluation of competition in these areas, including Form
477 mass market broadband data, A-CAM study area boundary data, A-CAM
modeling data, and geocoded location data submitted to USAC. We invite
commenters to identify specific data sources that could be useful to
our inquiry and to explain their utility.
55. The Commission also found that sales of TDM-based BDS by price
cap carriers were declining due to product substitution, including
customer loss to cable operators and other competitive providers. To
what extent are purchasers substituting packet-based services for TDM-
based services in A-CAM areas? Are TDM-based services declining in A-
CAM areas at a rate similar to the decline in price cap areas? The
Commission found declining prices for packet-based BDS across all
bandwidths in price cap areas to be evidence of competitive conditions.
Have prices for packet-based BDS in A-CAM areas also declined across
all bandwidths? Are lower bandwidth packet-based services (at or below
the level of a DS3) experiencing price changes in A-CAM areas as in
price cap areas?
56. We recognize that price cap carriers' provision of these
services was generally relieved of ex ante pricing regulation prior to
the BDS Order in a series of forbearance decisions. In contrast, A-CAM
carriers provide these services subject to rate-of-return regulation.
Would removing ex ante pricing regulation for these services for
electing A-CAM carriers encourage competitive entry and network
investment and provide an incentive for the transition to packet-based
technologies as we found to be the case for price cap carriers? In the
foregoing, we seek comment on the parameters of this potential
transition. Are there other issues we should consider as we evaluate
whether to remove ex ante pricing regulation for all packet-based and
TDM-based services providing bandwidth in excess of a DS3 offered by
electing A-CAM carriers?
57. We seek comment on granting forbearance from section 203
tariffing requirements for A-CAM carriers' provision of certain BDS
after they elect incentive regulation. In the BDS Order, the Commission
granted forbearance from the application of section 203 to each price
cap LEC in its provision of any packet-based BDS and of circuit-based
BDS above the DS3 bandwidth level. The Commission also granted
forbearance from the application of section 203 to price cap incumbent
LECs in their provision of BDS that comprise transport pursuant to
section 69.709(a)(4) of the Commission's rules, and to DS1 and DS3 end
user channel termination services and any other special access services
currently tariffed in competitive counties or in non-competitive
counties previously subject to Phase II pricing flexibility. The
Commission concluded that ``[w]here a price cap LEC provides these
services in competitive markets, application of section 203, including
its tariffing requirement, is not necessary to ensure that the LEC's
charges, practices, classifications, or regulations are just,
reasonable, and not unjustly or unreasonably discriminatory. Nor is
application of section 203 necessary to protect consumers.''
58. While the Petition does not expressly request forbearance from
tariffing requirements, we seek comment on whether to de-tariff certain
electing A-CAM BDS offerings by granting forbearance from section 203
tariffing obligations. We seek comment on whether we should remove ex
ante pricing regulation of packet-based BDS and higher capacity TDM-
based services providing bandwidth in excess of a DS3 for A-CAM
carriers that elect incentive regulation. Would forbearing from the
tariffing requirement for these services meet the statutory criteria
set by section 10 of the Act? Would de-tariffing these services promote
competitive market conditions? Would de-tariffing reduce compliance
costs, increase regulatory flexibility, increase incentives to invest
in innovative products and services and thereby facilitate the
technology transitions, or otherwise be in the public interest as the
Petition asserts? If the Commission decides to forbear from section
203, should it mandate or simply allow de-tariffing? Would mandatory
de-tariffing further promote competition and drive down prices by
requiring electing carriers to negotiate agreements to provide the de-
tariffed services that they offer?
[[Page 22932]]
V. Transition Mechanisms
59. We seek comment on how to transition electing A-CAM carriers
and the areas they serve if the Commission adopts a new lighter touch
regulatory framework for their provision of BDS. The BDS Order provided
certain mechanisms to facilitate the transition to the new regulatory
framework that it established for price cap carriers. These mechanisms
included a thirty-six month transition period in which de-tariffing is
permitted but not mandated, a six month freeze of tariffed rates for
end-user channel terminations in newly deregulated counties, and a
grandfathering of existing contractual or other long-term BDS
arrangements. We seek comment on the appropriateness of these and other
mechanisms to aid in the transition of electing A-CAM areas to any new
regulatory framework we establish for them. Are there other transition
issues and mechanisms that may be unique to A-CAM carriers and the
areas they serve that would help ensure an orderly transition? For
example, should the Commission consider any additional mechanisms that
would facilitate transitions for electing A-CAM carriers that
participate in NECA pooling arrangements?
VI. Other Carriers
60. We propose to offer the opportunity to elect the same type of
regulatory relief that we propose to provide to electing A-CAM carriers
to other rate-of-return carriers that currently receive fixed universal
service support, rather than receiving support based on their costs.
Such carriers include traditional rate-of-return carriers that are
affiliated with price cap carriers and are therefore receiving support
based on the Connect America Cost Model (CACM); rate-of-return carriers
participating in the Commission's ``Alaska Plan''; and carriers that
accept further offers of A-CAM support.
61. Like A-CAM carriers, the members of each of these three groups
of rate-of-return carriers all receive non-cost-based universal service
support and therefore are routinely required to prepare cost studies
only for their BDS. What are the costs and benefits of relieving them
of existing pricing regulations and allowing them to elect the type of
incentive pricing regulation we propose? Should we modify our proposed
incentive regulation in any way to reflect differences in any of these
types of carriers' circumstances? Are there any other types of carriers
that should be eligible for our incentive regulation proposal and, if
so, based on what rationale?
VII. ITTA/USTelecom Petition
62. Throughout this NPRM, we seek comment on various aspects of the
Petition for rulemaking filed by ITTA and USTelecom. However, the
Petition differs in some ways from what we propose in this NPRM. Most
fundamentally, it proposes that subject to certain conditions we simply
allow model-based carriers to elect the same regulatory framework that
the BDS Order provided for price cap carriers. It also proposes
providing electing A-CAM carriers an opportunity for a one-time
unfreezing of category relationships for purposes of jurisdictional
separations. To the extent we have not already done so, we invite
comment on the Petition and each of the proposals made therein.
VIII. Proposed Rule Changes
63. We seek comment on the proposed rule changes that can be found
in Appendix A. Those rule changes largely track the proposals made in
this NPRM. They also include some corrections to what appear to be
inaccuracies in our current rules. These proposed changes include
changing (1) the cross reference to Sec. 61.3(aa) in Sec. 51.903(g)
to Sec. 61.3(bb), (2) the cross reference to Sec. 61.3(ee) in Sec.
61.41(d) to Sec. 61.3(ff), (3) the cross reference to Sec. 61.3(x) in
Sec. 69.114 to Sec. 61.3(ff), and (4) the cross reference to Sec.
69.801(g) in Sec. 69.805(a) to Sec. 69.801(h). These cross references
have been rendered inaccurate because of changes in the definitions
contained in Sec. 61.3 that occurred in other rulemaking proceedings
or because they were incorrectly stated when added to our rules.
IX. Procedural Matters
64. This proceeding shall be treated as a ``permit-but-disclose''
proceeding in accordance with the Commission's ex parte rules. Persons
making ex parte presentations must file a copy of any written
presentation or a memorandum summarizing any oral presentation within
two business days after the presentation (unless a different deadline
applicable to the Sunshine period applies). Persons making oral ex
parte presentations are reminded that memoranda summarizing the
presentation must (1) list all persons attending or otherwise
participating in the meeting at which the ex parte presentation was
made, and (2) summarize all data presented and arguments made during
the presentation. If the presentation consisted in whole or in part of
the presentation of data or arguments already reflected in the
presenter's written comments, memoranda or other filings in the
proceeding, the presenter may provide citations to such data or
arguments in his or her prior comments, memoranda, or other filings
(specifying the relevant page and/or paragraph numbers where such data
or arguments can be found) in lieu of summarizing them in the
memorandum. Documents shown or given to Commission staff during ex
parte meetings are deemed to be written ex parte presentations and must
be filed consistent with rule 1.1206(b). In proceedings governed by
Rule 1.49(f) or for which the Commission has made available a method of
electronic filing, written ex parte presentations and memoranda
summarizing oral ex parte presentations, and all attachments thereto,
must be filed through the electronic comment filing system available
for that proceeding, and must be filed in their native format (e.g.,
.doc, .xml, .ppt, searchable .pdf). Participants in this proceeding
should familiarize themselves with the Commission's ex parte rules.
A. Initial Regulatory Flexibility Analysis
65. Pursuant to the Regulatory Flexibility Act (RFA), the
Commission has prepared an Initial Regulatory Flexibility Analysis
(IRFA) of the possible significant economic impact on small entities of
the policies and actions considered in this Notice of Proposed
Rulemaking. The text of the IRFA is set forth in Appendix B. Written
public comments are requested on this IRFA. Comments must be identified
as responses to the IRFA and must be filed by the deadlines for comment
on the Notice of Proposed Rulemaking. The Commission's Consumer and
Governmental Affairs Bureau, Reference Information Center, will send a
copy of this Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, including the IRFA, to the
Chief Counsel for Advocacy of the Small Business Administration (SBA).
B. Paperwork Reduction Act
66. This document may contain proposed new or modified information
collection requirements. The Commission, as part of its continuing
effort to reduce paperwork burdens, invites the general public and the
Office of Management and Budget (OMB) to comment on the information
collection requirements contained in this document, as required by the
Paperwork Reduction Act of 1995, Public Law 104-13. In addition,
pursuant to the Small Business Paperwork Relief Act of 2002,
[[Page 22933]]
Public Law 107-198, we seek specific comment on how we might further
reduce the information collection burden for small business concerns
with fewer than 25 employees.
X. Initial Regulatory Flexibility Analysis
67. As required by the Regulatory Flexibility Act of 1980, as
amended (RFA), the Commission has prepared this Initial Regulatory
Flexibility Analysis (IRFA) of the possible significant economic impact
on small entities by the policies and rules proposed in this Notice of
Proposed Rulemaking (NPRM). The Commission requests written public
comments on this IRFA. Comments must be identified as responses to the
IRFA and must be filed by the deadlines for comments provided on the
first page of the NPRM. The Commission will send a copy of the NPRM,
including this IRFA, to the Chief Counsel for Advocacy of the Small
Business Administration (SBA). In addition, the NPRM and IRFA (or
summaries thereof) will be published in the Federal Register.
A. Need for, and Objectives of, the Proposed Rules
68. In this NPRM, we propose changes to, and seek comment on, our
rate-of-return and business data services rules as they are applied to
rate-of-return carriers that receive universal service support based on
the Alternative-Connect America Cost Model (A-CAM), or under the
Commission's universal service support mechanism for Alaska-based
carriers (Alaska Plan), or is an affiliate of a price cap local
exchange carrier operating pursuant to a waiver of Sec. 61.41 of our
rules. In the NPRM, the Commission proposes to adopt a form of
incentive regulation for A-CAM carriers' provision of business data
services (BDS), conduct a market analysis to evaluate the
characteristics of BDS markets served by A-CAM carriers, and adopt a
new lighter touch regulatory framework for A-CAM carriers' BDS that in
most respects parallels the framework recently adopted for price cap
carriers in the BDS Order.
B. Legal Basis
69. The legal basis for any action that may be taken pursuant to
this NPRM is contained in sections 1, 4(i), 10, and 201(b) of the
Communications Act of 1934, as amended, 47 U.S.C. 151, 154(i), 160, and
201(b).
C. Description and Estimate of the Number of Small Entities to Which
the Proposed Rules Will Apply
70. The RFA directs agencies to provide a description of, and where
feasible, an estimate of the number of small entities that may be
affected by the proposed rules and by the rule revisions on which the
NPRM seeks comment, if adopted. The RFA generally defines the term
``small entity'' as having the same meaning as the terms ``small
business,'' ``small organization,'' and ``small governmental
jurisdiction.'' In addition, the term ``small business'' has the same
meaning as the term ``small-business concern'' under the Small Business
Act. A ``small-business concern'' is one which: (1) Is independently
owned and operated; (2) is not dominant in its field of operation; and
(3) satisfies any additional criteria established by the SBA.
1. Total Small Entities
71. Small Businesses, Small Organizations, Small Governmental
Jurisdictions. Our actions, over time, may affect small entities that
are not easily categorized at present. We therefore describe here, at
the outset, three broad groups of small entities that could be directly
affected herein. First, while there are industry specific size
standards for small businesses that are used in the regulatory
flexibility analysis, according to data from the SBA's Office of
Advocacy, in general a small business is an independent business having
fewer than 500 employees. These types of small businesses represent
99.9% of all businesses in the United States which translates to 28.8
million businesses.
72. Next, the type of small entity described as a ``small
organization'' is generally ``any not-for-profit enterprise which is
independently owned and operated and is not dominant in its field.''
Nationwide, as of August 2016, there were approximately 356,494 small
organizations based on registration and tax data filed by nonprofits
with the Internal Revenue Service (IRS).
73. Finally, the small entity described as a ``small governmental
jurisdiction'' is defined generally as ``governments of cities, towns,
townships, villages, school districts, or special districts, with a
population of less than fifty thousand.'' U.S. Census Bureau data from
the 2012 Census of Governments indicates that there were 90,056 local
governmental jurisdictions consisting of general purpose governments
and special purpose governments in the United States. Of this number
there were 37,132 general purpose governments (county, municipal and
town or township) with populations of less than 50,000 and 12,184
special purpose governments (independent school districts and special
districts) with populations of less than 50,000. The 2012 U.S. Census
Bureau data for most types of governments in the local government
category shows that the majority of these governments have populations
of less than 50,000. Based on these data we estimate that at least
49,316 local government jurisdictions fall in the category of ``small
governmental jurisdictions.''
2. Broadband Internet Access Service Providers
74. Internet Service Providers (Broadband). Broadband internet
service providers include wired (e.g., cable, DSL) and VoIP service
providers using their own operated wired telecommunications
infrastructure fall in the category of Wired Telecommunication
Carriers. Wired Telecommunications Carriers are comprised of
establishments primarily engaged in operating and/or providing access
to transmission facilities and infrastructure that they own and/or
lease for the transmission of voice, data, text, sound, and video using
wired telecommunications networks. Transmission facilities may be based
on a single technology or a combination of technologies. The SBA size
standard for this category classifies a business as small if it has
1,500 or fewer employees. U.S. Census data for 2012 show that there
were 3,117 firms that operated that year. Of this total, 3,083 operated
with fewer than 1,000 employees. Consequently, under this size standard
the majority of firms in this industry can be considered small.
3. Wireline Providers
75. Wired Telecommunications Carriers. The U.S. Census Bureau
defines this industry as ``establishments primarily engaged in
operating and/or providing access to transmission facilities and
infrastructure that they own and/or lease for the transmission of
voice, data, text, sound, and video using wired communications
networks. Transmission facilities may be based on a single technology
or a combination of technologies. Establishments in this industry use
the wired telecommunications network facilities that they operate to
provide a variety of services, such as wired telephony services,
including VoIP services, wired (cable) audio and video programming
distribution, and wired broadband internet services. By exception,
establishments providing satellite
[[Page 22934]]
television distribution services using facilities and infrastructure
that they operate are included in this industry.'' The SBA has
developed a small business size standard for Wired Telecommunications
Carriers, which consists of all such companies having 1,500 or fewer
employees. Census data for 2012 show that there were 3,117 firms that
operated that year. Of this total, 3,083 operated with fewer than 1,000
employees. Thus, under this size standard, the majority of firms in
this industry can be considered small.
76. Incumbent Local Exchange Carriers (Incumbent LECs). Neither the
Commission nor the SBA has developed a small business size standard
specifically for incumbent LEC services. The closest applicable size
standard under SBA rules is for the category Wired Telecommunications
Carriers as defined above. Under that size standard, such a business is
small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees. According to Commission data,
3,117 firms operated in that year. Of this total, 3,083 operated with
fewer than 1,000 employees. Consequently, the Commission estimates that
most providers of incumbent local exchange service are small businesses
that may be affected by the rules and policies adopted. A total of
1,307 firms reported that they were incumbent local exchange service
providers. Of this total, an estimated 1,006 have 1,500 or fewer
employees.
77. Competitive Local Exchange Carriers (Competitive LECs),
Competitive Access Providers (CAPs), Shared-Tenant Service Providers,
and Other Local Service Providers. Neither the Commission nor the SBA
has developed a small business size standard specifically for these
service providers. The appropriate NAICS Code category is Wired
Telecommunications Carriers, as defined above. Under that size
standard, such a business is small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees.
U.S. Census data for 2012 indicate that 3,117 firms operated during
that year. Of that number, 3,083 operated with fewer than 1,000
employees. Based on this data, the Commission concludes that the
majority of Competitive LECS, CAPs, Shared-Tenant Service Providers,
and Other Local Service Providers, are small entities. According to
Commission data, 1,442 carriers reported that they were engaged in the
provision of either competitive local exchange services or competitive
access provider services. Of these 1,442 carriers, an estimated 1,256
have 1,500 or fewer employees. In addition, 17 carriers have reported
that they are Shared-Tenant Service Providers, and all 17 are estimated
to have 1,500 or fewer employees. Also, 72 carriers have reported that
they are Other Local Service Providers. Of this total, 70 have 1,500 or
fewer employees. Consequently, based on internally researched FCC data,
the Commission estimates that most providers of competitive local
exchange service, competitive access providers, Shared-Tenant Service
Providers, and Other Local Service Providers are small entities.
78. We have included small incumbent LECs in this present RFA
analysis. As noted above, a ``small business'' under the RFA is one
that, inter alia, meets the pertinent small business size standard
(e.g., a telephone communications business having 1,500 or fewer
employees), and ``is not dominant in its field of operation.'' The
SBA's Office of Advocacy contends that, for RFA purposes, small
incumbent LECs are not dominant in their field of operation because any
such dominance is not ``national'' in scope. We have therefore included
small incumbent LECs in this RFA analysis, although we emphasize that
this RFA action has no effect on Commission analyses and determinations
in other, non-RFA contexts.
79. Interexchange Carriers (IXCs). Neither the Commission nor the
SBA has developed a definition for Interexchange Carriers. The closest
NAICS Code category is Wired Telecommunications Carriers as defined
above. The applicable size standard under SBA rules is that such a
business is small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees. U.S. Census data
for 2012 indicates that 3,117 firms operated during that year. Of that
number, 3,083 operated with fewer than 1,000 employees. According to
internally developed Commission data, 359 companies reported that their
primary telecommunications service activity was the provision of
interexchange services. Of this total, an estimated 317 have 1,500 or
fewer employees. Consequently, the Commission estimates that the
majority of IXCs are small entities that may be affected by our
proposed rules.
80. Local Resellers. The SBA has developed a small business size
standard for the category of Telecommunications Resellers. The
Telecommunications Resellers industry comprises establishments engaged
in purchasing access and network capacity from owners and operators of
telecommunications networks and reselling wired and wireless
telecommunications services (except satellite) to businesses and
households. Establishments in this industry resell telecommunications;
they do not operate transmission facilities and infrastructure. Mobile
virtual network operators (MVNOs) are included in this industry. Under
that size standard, such a business is small if it has 1,500 or fewer
employees. Census data for 2012 show that 1,341 firms provided resale
services during that year. Of that number, all operated with fewer than
1,000 employees. Thus, under this category and the associated small
business size standard, the majority of these prepaid calling card
providers can be considered small entities.
81. Toll Resellers. The Commission has not developed a definition
for Toll Resellers. The closest NAICS Code Category is
Telecommunications Resellers. The Telecommunications Resellers industry
comprises establishments engaged in purchasing access and network
capacity from owners and operators of telecommunications networks and
reselling wired and wireless telecommunications services (except
satellite) to businesses and households. Establishments in this
industry resell telecommunications; they do not operate transmission
facilities and infrastructure. Mobile virtual network operators (MVNOs)
are included in this industry. The SBA has developed a small business
size standard for the category of Telecommunications Resellers. Under
that size standard, such a business is small if it has 1,500 or fewer
employees. Census data for 2012 show that 1,341 firms provided resale
services during that year. Of that number, 1,341 operated with fewer
than 1,000 employees. Thus, under this category and the associated
small business size standard, the majority of these resellers can be
considered small entities. According to Commission data, 881 carriers
have reported that they are engaged in the provision of toll resale
services. Of this total, an estimated 857 have 1,500 or fewer
employees. Consequently, the Commission estimates that the majority of
toll resellers are small entities.
82. Other Toll Carriers. Neither the Commission nor the SBA has
developed a definition for small businesses specifically applicable to
Other Toll Carriers. This category includes toll carriers that do not
fall within the categories of interexchange carriers, operator service
providers, prepaid calling card providers, satellite service carriers,
or toll resellers. The closest applicable NAICS Code category is for
Wired Telecommunications Carriers as defined above. Under the
applicable SBA size standard, such a business is small if it has 1,500
or fewer employees. Census data for 2012 show that there
[[Page 22935]]
were 3,117 firms that operated that year. Of this total, 3,083 operated
with fewer than 1,000 employees. Thus, under this category and the
associated small business size standard, the majority of Other Toll
Carriers can be considered small. According to internally developed
Commission data, 284 companies reported that their primary
telecommunications service activity was the provision of other toll
carriage. Of these, an estimated 279 have 1,500 or fewer employees.
Consequently, the Commission estimates that most Other Toll Carriers
are small entities that may be affected by rules adopted pursuant to
the Second Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking.
83. Operator Service Providers (OSPs). Neither the Commission nor
the SBA has developed a small business size standard specifically for
operator service providers. The appropriate size standard under SBA
rules is for the category Wired Telecommunications Carriers. Under that
size standard, such a business is small if it has 1,500 or fewer
employees. According to Commission data, 33 carriers have reported that
they are engaged in the provision of operator services. Of these, an
estimated 31 have 1,500 or fewer employees and two have more than 1,500
employees. Consequently, the Commission estimates that the majority of
OSPs are small entities.
84. Prepaid Calling Card Providers. The SBA has developed a
definition for small businesses within the category of
Telecommunications Resellers. Under that SBA definition, such a
business is small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees. According to the
Commission's Form 499 Filer Database, 500 companies reported that they
were engaged in the provision of prepaid calling cards. The Commission
does not have data regarding how many of these 500 companies have 1,500
or fewer employees. Consequently, the Commission estimates that there
are 500 or fewer prepaid calling card providers that may be affected by
the rules.
4. Wireless Providers--Fixed and Mobile
85. Wireless Telecommunications Carriers (except Satellite). This
industry comprises establishments engaged in operating and maintaining
switching and transmission facilities to provide communications via the
airwaves. Establishments in this industry have spectrum licenses and
provide services using that spectrum, such as cellular services, paging
services, wireless internet access, and wireless video services. The
appropriate size standard under SBA rules is that such a business is
small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees. For this industry, U.S.
Census data for 2012 show that there were 967 firms that operated for
the entire year. Of this total, 955 firms had employment of 999 or
fewer employees and 12 had employment of 1000 employees or more. Thus
under this category and the associated size standard, the Commission
estimates that the majority of wireless telecommunications carriers
(except satellite) are small entities.
86. The Commission's own data--available in its Universal Licensing
System--indicate that, as of October 25, 2016, there are 280 Cellular
licensees that will be affected by our actions today. The Commission
does not know how many of these licensees are small, as the Commission
does not collect that information for these types of entities.
Similarly, according to internally developed Commission data, 413
carriers reported that they were engaged in the provision of wireless
telephony, including cellular service, Personal Communications Service,
and Specialized Mobile Radio Telephony services. Of this total, an
estimated 261 have 1,500 or fewer employees, and 152 have more than
1,500 employees. Thus, using available data, we estimate that the
majority of wireless firms can be considered small.
87. Wireless Communications Services. This service can be used for
fixed, mobile, radiolocation, and digital audio broadcasting satellite
uses. The Commission defined ``small business'' for the wireless
communications services (WCS) auction as an entity with average gross
revenues of $40 million for each of the three preceding years, and a
``very small business'' as an entity with average gross revenues of $15
million for each of the three preceding years. The SBA has approved
these definitions.
88. Wireless Telephony. Wireless telephony includes cellular,
personal communications services, and specialized mobile radio
telephony carriers. As noted, the SBA has developed a small business
size standard for Wireless Telecommunications Carriers (except
Satellite). Under the SBA small business size standard, a business is
small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees. According to Commission data,
413 carriers reported that they were engaged in wireless telephony. Of
these, an estimated 261 have 1,500 or fewer employees and 152 have more
than 1,500 employees. Therefore, a little less than one third of these
entities can be considered small.
5. Satellite Service Providers
89. Satellite Telecommunications Providers. This category comprises
firms ``primarily engaged in providing telecommunications services to
other establishments in the telecommunications and broadcasting
industries by forwarding and receiving communications signals via a
system of satellites or reselling satellite telecommunications.''
Satellite telecommunications service providers include satellite and
earth station operators. The category has a small business size
standard of $32.5 million or less in average annual receipts, under SBA
rules. For this category, U.S. Census Bureau data for 2012 show that
there were a total of 333 firms that operated for the entire year. Of
this total, 299 firms had annual receipts of less than $25 million.
Consequently, we estimate that the majority of satellite
telecommunications providers are small entities.
6. Cable Service Providers
90. Because section 706 requires us to monitor the deployment of
broadband using any technology, we anticipate that some broadband
service providers may not provide telephone service. Accordingly, we
describe below other types of firms that may provide broadband
services, including cable companies, MDS providers, and utilities,
among others.
91. Cable and Other Subscription Programming. This industry
comprises establishments primarily engaged in operating studios and
facilities for the broadcasting of programs on a subscription or fee
basis. The broadcast programming is typically narrowcast in nature
(e.g. limited format, such as news, sports, education, or youth-
oriented). These establishments produce programming in their own
facilities or acquire programming from external sources. The
programming material is usually delivered to a third party, such as
cable systems or direct-to-home satellite systems, for transmission to
viewers. The SBA has established a size standard for this industry
stating that a business in this industry is small if it has 1,500 or
fewer employees. The 2012 Economic Census indicates that 367 firms were
operational for that entire year. Of this total, 357 operated with less
than 1,000 employees. Accordingly we conclude that a substantial
majority of firms in this industry are small under the applicable SBA
size standard.
92. Cable Companies and Systems (Rate Regulation). The Commission
has developed its own small business size standards for the purpose of
cable rate
[[Page 22936]]
regulation. Under the Commission's rules, a ``small cable company'' is
one serving 400,000 or fewer subscribers nationwide. Industry data
indicate that there are currently 4,600 active cable systems in the
United States. Of this total, all but eleven cable operators nationwide
are small under the 400,000-subscriber size standard. In addition,
under the Commission's rate regulation rules, a ``small system'' is a
cable system serving 15,000 or fewer subscribers. Current Commission
records show 4,600 cable systems nationwide. Of this total, 3,900 cable
systems have fewer than 15,000 subscribers, and 700 systems have 15,000
or more subscribers, based on the same records. Thus, under this
standard as well, we estimate that most cable systems are small
entities.
93. Cable System Operators (Telecom Act Standard). The
Communications Act also contains a size standard for small cable system
operators, which is ``a cable operator that, directly or through an
affiliate, serves in the aggregate fewer than 1 percent of all
subscribers in the United States and is not affiliated with any entity
or entities whose gross annual revenues in the aggregate exceed
$250,000,000.'' There are approximately 52,403,705 cable video
subscribers in the United States today. Accordingly, an operator
serving fewer than 524,037 subscribers shall be deemed a small operator
if its annual revenues, when combined with the total annual revenues of
all its affiliates, do not exceed $250 million in the aggregate. Based
on available data, we find that all but nine incumbent cable operators
are small entities under this size standard. The Commission neither
requests nor collects information on whether cable system operators are
affiliated with entities whose gross annual revenues exceed $250
million. Although it seems certain that some of these cable system
operators are affiliated with entities whose gross annual revenues
exceed $250 million, we are unable at this time to estimate with
greater precision the number of cable system operators that would
qualify as small cable operators under the definition in the
Communications Act.
94. All Other Telecommunications. ``All Other Telecommunications''
is defined as follows: This U.S. industry is comprised of
establishments that are primarily engaged in providing specialized
telecommunications services, such as satellite tracking, communications
telemetry, and radar station operation. This industry also includes
establishments primarily engaged in providing satellite terminal
stations and associated facilities connected with one or more
terrestrial systems and capable of transmitting telecommunications to,
and receiving telecommunications from, satellite systems.
Establishments providing internet services or voice over internet
protocol (VoIP) services via client-supplied telecommunications
connections are also included in this industry. The SBA has developed a
small business size standard for ``All Other Telecommunications,''
which consists of all such firms with gross annual receipts of $32.5
million or less. For this category, census data for 2012 show that
there were 1,442 firms that operated for the entire year. Of these
firms, a total of 1,400 had gross annual receipts of less than $25
million. Consequently, we estimate that the majority of All Other
Telecommunications firms are small entities that might be affected by
our action.
7. Electric Power Generators, Transmitters, and Distributors
95. Electric Power Generators, Transmitters, and Distributors. This
U.S. industry is comprised of establishments that are primarily engaged
in providing specialized telecommunications services, such as satellite
tracking, communications telemetry, and radar station operation. This
industry also includes establishments primarily engaged in providing
satellite terminal stations and associated facilities connected with
one or more terrestrial systems and capable of transmitting
telecommunications to, and receiving telecommunications from, satellite
systems. Establishments providing internet services or voice over
internet protocol (VoIP) services via client-supplied
telecommunications connections are also included in this industry. The
closest applicable SBA category is ``All Other Telecommunications''.
The SBA's small business size standard for ``All Other
Telecommunications,'' consists of all such firms with gross annual
receipts of $32.5 million or less. For this category, U.S. Census data
for 2012 show that there were 1,442 firms that operated for the entire
year. Of these firms, a total of 1,400 had gross annual receipts of
less than $25 million. Consequently, we estimate that under this
category and the associated size standard the majority of these firms
can be considered small entities.
D. Description of Projected Reporting, Recordkeeping, and Other
Compliance Requirements for Small Entities
96. This NPRM proposes changes to, and seeks comment on, the
Commission's rate-of-return and business data services rules. The
objective of the proposed modifications is to reduce the unnecessary
regulatory burdens and inflexibility of rate-of-return regulation for
BDS services for A-CAM carriers, which are for the most part small
businesses. These rule modifications would provide additional
incentives for competitive entry, network investment and the migration
to IP-based network technologies and services. The NPRM seeks comment
on proposed rules that would generally reduce compliance requirements
for A-CAM carriers that choose to opt into the new incentive regulation
and regulatory framework for the provision of BDS.
97. Under the Commission's rate-of-return rules, rates for business
data services are based on costs derived from carrier-specific cost
studies which represent a significant compliance burden for A-CAM
carriers relative to their overall revenues. The NPRM proposes to
transition these carriers to a form of incentive regulation that will
enable these LECs to significantly reduce these compliance costs. The
NPRM also proposes a new regulatory framework for A-CAM carriers' BDS
that would in many cases eliminate ex ante pricing regulation and
tariffing requirements for carriers electing incentive regulation.
E. Steps Taken To Minimize the Significant Economic Impact on Small
Entities, and Significant Alternatives Considered
98. The RFA requires an agency to describe any significant
alternatives that it has considered in reaching its proposed approach,
which may include the following four alternatives (among others): (1)
The establishment of differing compliance or reporting requirements or
timetables that take into account the resources available to small
entities; (2) the clarification, consolidation, or simplification of
compliance and reporting requirements under the rules for such small
entities; (3) the use of performance rather than design standards; and
(4) an exemption from coverage of the rule, or any part thereof, for
such small entities.
99. The rule changes proposed by the NPRM would reduce the economic
impact of the Commission's rules on A-CAM carriers that elect incentive
regulation in the following ways. Electing A-CAM carriers would no
longer be required to prepare annual cost studies to justify their BDS
rates. Such carriers would also be freed of ex ante pricing regulation
for many of their BDS offerings, including packet-based BDS, circuit-
based BDS above a DS3
[[Page 22937]]
bandwidth (about 45 Mbps) such as OCn services, and circuit-based end
user channel terminations (e.g. DS1 and DS3) in geographic areas deemed
to be competitive by a competitive market test. These proposed rule
changes represent alternatives to the Commission's current rules that
would significantly minimize the economic impact of those rules on
electing A-CAM LECs. Finally, we seek comment as to any additional
economic burden incurred by small entities that may result from the
rule changes proposed in the NPRM.
F. Federal Rules That May Duplicate, Overlap, or Conflict With the
Proposed Rules
100. None.
XI. Ordering Clauses
101. Accordingly, it is ordered, pursuant to sections 1, 4(i), 10,
and 201(b) of the Communication Act of 1934, as amended, 47 U.S.C. 151,
154(i), 160, and 201(b) that the Petition for Rulemaking filed by ITTA
and USTelecom in this proceeding is granted to the extent described
herein.
102. It is further ordered, pursuant to sections 1, 4(i), 10, and
201(b) of the Communication Act of 1934, as amended, 47 U.S.C. 151,
154(i), 160, and 201(b) that this Notice of Proposed Rulemaking is
adopted.
103. It is further ordered, Pursuant to Section 220(i) of the
Communications Act, 47 U.S.C. 220(i), that notice be given to each
state commission of the above rulemaking proceeding, and that the
Secretary shall serve a copy of this NPRM on each state commission.
104. It is further ordered that the Commission's Consumer and
Governmental Affairs Bureau, Reference Information Center, shall send a
copy of this Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, including the Initial
Regulatory Flexibility Analysis, to the Chief Counsel for Advocacy of
the Small Business Administration.
List of Subjects
47 CFR Part 1
Communications common carriers, Equal employment opportunity,
Reporting and recordkeeping requirements, Telecommunications,
Television.
47 CFR Part 32
Communications common carriers, Reporting and recordkeeping
requirements, Telephone, Uniform System of Accounts.
47 CFR Part 51
Communications common carriers, Telecommunications.
47 CFR Parts 61 and 69
Communications common carriers, Reporting and recordkeeping
requirements, Telephone.
Federal Communications Commission.
Marlene Dortch,
Secretary.
Proposed Rules
For the reasons discussed in the preamble, the Federal
Communications Commission proposes to amend 47 CFR parts 1, 32, 51, 61
and 69 as follows:
PART 1--PRACTICE AND PROCEDURE
0
1. The authority citation for part 1 is revised to read as follows:
Authority: 47 U.S.C. 151, 154(i), 154(j), 155, 157, 225, 227,
303(r), 309, 1403, 1404, 1451, and 1452.
0
2. Section 1.1409 is amended by revising paragraph (g) to read as
follows:
Sec. 1.1409 Commission consideration of the complaint.
* * * * *
(g) A price cap company, or a rate-of-return carrier electing to
provide service pursuant to Sec. 61.50 of this chapter, opts-out of
Part 32 may calculate attachment rates for its poles, ducts, conduits,
and rights of way using either Part 32 accounting data or GAAP
accounting data. A company using GAAP accounting data to compute rates
to attach to its poles, ducts, conduits, and rights of way in any of
the first twelve years after opting-out must adjust (increase or
decrease) its annually computed GAAP-based rates by an Implementation
Rate Difference for each of the remaining years in the period. The
Implementation Rate Difference means the difference between attachment
rates calculated by the carrier under Part 32 and under GAAP as of the
last full year preceding the carrier's initial opting-out of Part 32
USOA accounting requirements.
PART 32--UNIFORM SYSTEM OF ACCOUNTS FOR TELECOMMUNICATIONS
COMPANIES
0
3. The authority citation for part 32 continues to read as follows:
Authority: 47 U.S.C. 219, 220 as amended, unless otherwise
noted.
0
4. Section 32.1 is revised to read as follows:
Sec. 32.1 Background
The revised Uniform System of Accounts (USOA) is a historical
financial accounting system which reports the results of operational
and financial events in a manner which enables both management and
regulators to assess these results within a specified accounting
period. The USOA also provides the financial community and others with
financial performance results. In order for an accounting system to
fulfill these purposes, it must exhibit consistency and stability in
financial reporting (including the results published for regulatory
purposes). Accordingly, the USOA has been designed to reflect stable,
recurring financial data based to the extent regulatory considerations
permit upon the consistency of the well-established body of accounting
theories and principles commonly referred to as generally accepted
accounting principles (GAAP). The rules of this part, and any other
rules or orders that are derivative of or dependent on these Part 32
rules, do not apply to price cap companies, and rate-of-return
telephone companies offering business data services pursuant to Sec.
61.50 of this chapter, that have opted-out of USOA requirements
pursuant to the conditions specified by the Commission in section
32.11(g).
0
5. Section 32.11 is amended by revising paragraph (g) to read as
follows:
Sec. 32.11 Companies Subject to this part.
* * * * *
(g) Notwithstanding subsection (a), a price cap company, or a rate-
of-return telephone company offering business data services pursuant to
Sec. 61.50 of this chapter, that elects to calculate its pole
attachment rates pursuant to section 1.1409(g) of this chapter will not
be subject to this Uniform System of Accounts.
PART 51--INTERCONNECTION
0
6. The authority citation for part 51 continues to read as follows:
Authority: 47 U.S.C. 151-55, 201-05, 207-09, 218, 220, 225-27,
251-54, 256, 271, 303(r), 332, 1302.
0
7. Section 51.903 is amended by revising paragraph (g) to read:
Sec. 51.903 Definitions.
* * * * *
(g) Rate-of-Return Carrier is any incumbent local exchange carrier
not subject to price cap regulation as that term is defined in Sec.
61.3(bb) of this chapter, but only with respect to the
[[Page 22938]]
territory in which it operates as an incumbent local exchange carrier.
* * * * *
PART 61--TARIFFS
0
8. The authority citation for part 61 continues to read as follows:
Authority: Secs. 1, 4(i), 4(j), 201-05 and 403 of the
Communications Act of 1934, as amended; 47 U.S.C. 151, 154(i),
154(j), 201-05 and 403, unless otherwise noted.
0
9. Section 61.41 is amended by revising paragraph (d) and adding
paragraph (f) to read as follows:
Sec. 61.41 Price cap requirements generally.
* * * * *
(d) Except as provided in paragraph (e) of this section, local
exchange carriers that become subject to price cap regulation as that
term is defined in Sec. 61.3(ff) shall not be eligible to withdraw
from such regulation.
* * * * *
(f) Notwithstanding the requirements of paragraphs (c) and (d) of
this section, a telephone company subject to rate-of-return regulation
that is affiliated with a price cap local exchange carrier may provide
business data services pursuant to Sec. 61.50 without converting other
services to price cap regulation.
0
10. Section 61.50 is added to read as follows:
Sec. 61.50 Incentive regulation of rate-of-return carrier provision
of business data services.
(a) A rate-of-return carrier, as defined in Sec. 51.903(g), has
the option to offer business data services to customers pursuant to
this section if the carrier
(1) Receives universal service payments pursuant to the
Alternative-Connect America Cost Model pursuant to Sec. 54.311;
(2) Is an affiliate of a price cap local exchange carrier operating
pursuant to a waiver of Sec. 61.41; or
(3) Receives universal service payments pursuant to Sec. 54.306.
(b) A rate-of-return carrier may not elect to offer business data
services to customers pursuant to this section unless it notifies the
Chief of the Wireline Competition Bureau at least 120 days before the
effective date of the election. Carriers may only elect this option to
be effective on July 1, [year].
(c) A rate-of-return carrier may elect to offer business data
services pursuant to this section only if all affiliated rate-of-return
carriers make the election.
(d) A rate-of-return carrier electing to offer business data
services under this section may continue to participate in the NECA
Traffic Sensitive Pool for access services other than business data
services.
(e) A rate-of-return carrier electing to offer business data
services pursuant to this section shall employ the procedures outlined
in Sec. Sec. 61.41 through .49 to adjust its indexes to the extent
those sections are applicable to business data services, except that:
(1) For the special access basket specified in Sec. 61.42(d)(5),
the value of X for local exchange carriers offering service under this
section shall be 2.0% effective July 1, [year]; and
(2) Exogenous costs shall be allocated to business data services
based on relative revenues, including any universal service support
amounts.
(f) Tariffs offering business data services pursuant to this
section may offer those business data services at different rates in
different study areas.
(g) A rate-of-return carrier offering business data services
pursuant to this section may make a low-end adjustment pursuant to
Sec. 61.45(d)(1)(vii) of this subpart unless it:
(1) Exercises the regulatory relief pursuant to paragraph (j) of
this section in any part of its service region; or
(2) Exercises the option to use Generally Accepted Accounting
Principles rather than the Part 32 Uniform System of Accounts pursuant
to Sec. 32.11(g).
(h) Rate-of-return carriers electing to offer business data
services pursuant to this section may offer transport and end user
channel terminations that include:
(1) Volume and term discounts;
(2) Contract-based tariffs, provided that:
(i) Contract-based tariff services are made generally available to
all similarly situated customers;
(ii) The rate-of-return carrier excludes all contract-based tariff
offerings from incentive regulation pursuant to Sec. 61.42(f) of this
subpart;
(3) Ability to file tariff revisions on at least one day's notice,
notwithstanding the notice requirements for tariff filings specified in
Sec. 61.58 of this chapter.
(j) A rate-of-return carrier electing to offer business data
services pursuant to this section shall comply with the requirements of
section 69.805 of this Chapter.
(k) The regulation of other services offered by a rate-of-return
carrier that offers business data services pursuant to this section
shall not be modified as a result of the requirements of this section.
0
11. Section 61.55 is amended by revising paragraph (a) to read as
follows:
Sec. 61.55 Contract-based tariffs.
(a) This section shall apply to price cap local exchange carriers
permitted to offer contract-based tariffs under Sec. 1.776 or Sec.
69.805 of this chapter, as well as to the offering of business data
services by rate-of-return carriers pursuant to Sec. 61.50 of this
part.
* * * * *
PART 69--ACCESS CHARGES
0
12. The authority citation for part 69 continues to read as follows:
Authority: 47 U.S.C. 154, 201, 202, 203, 205, 218, 220, 254,
403.
0
13. Section 69.114 is amended by revising paragraph (a) to read as
follows:
Sec. 69.114 Special Access.
(a) Appropriate subelements shall be established for the use of
equipment or facilities that are assigned to the Special Access element
for purposes of apportioning net investment, or that are equivalent to
such equipment or facilities for companies subject to price cap
regulation as that term is defined in Sec. 61.3(ff) of this chapter.
* * * * *
0
14. Section 69.805 is amended by revising paragraph (a) to read as
follows:
Sec. 69.805 Prohibition on certain non-disclosure agreement
conditions.
(a) In markets deemed non-competitive, buyers and sellers of
business data services shall not enter into a tariff, contract-based
tariff, or commercial agreement, including but not limited to master
service agreement, that contains a non-disclosure agreement as defined
in Sec. 69.801(h), that restricts or prohibits disclosure of
information to the Commission, or requires a prior request or legal
compulsion by the Commission to effect such disclosure.
* * * * *
[FR Doc. 2018-10338 Filed 5-16-18; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6712-01-P