Restoring Internet Freedom, 7852-7922 [2018-03464]
Download as PDF
7852
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS
COMMISSION
47 CFR Parts 1, 8, and 20
[WC Docket No. 17–108; FCC 17–166]
Restoring Internet Freedom
Federal Communications
Commission.
ACTION: Final rule.
AGENCY:
In this document, the Federal
Communications Commission
(Commission) returns to the light-touch
regulatory scheme that enabled the
internet to develop and thrive for nearly
two decades. The Commission restores
the classification of broadband internet
access service as a lightly-regulated
information service and reinstates the
private mobile service classification of
mobile broadband internet access
service. The Restoring Internet Freedom
Order requires internet service
providers (ISPs) to disclose information
about their network management
practices, performance characteristics,
and commercial terms of service.
Finding that transparency is sufficient
to protect the openness of the internet
and that conduct rules have greater
costs than benefits, the Order eliminates
the conduct rules imposed by the Title
II Order.
DATES: Effective date: April 23, 2018,
except for amendatory instructions 2, 3,
5, 6, and 8, which are delayed as
follows. The FCC will publish a
document in the Federal Register
announcing the effective date(s) of the
delayed amendatory instructions, which
are contingent on OMB approval of the
modified information collection
requirements in 47 CFR 8.1 (amendatory
instruction 5). The Declaratory Ruling,
Report and Order, and Order will also
be effective upon the date announced in
that same document.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
Ramesh Nagarajan, Competition Policy
Division, Wireline Competition Bureau,
at (202) 418–2582, ramesh.nagarajan@
fcc.gov. For additional information
concerning the Paperwork Reduction
Act information collection requirements
contained in this document, send an
email to PRA@fcc.gov or contact Nicole
Ongele at (202) 418–2991.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: This is a
summary of the Commission’s
Declaratory Ruling, Report and Order,
and Order (‘‘Restoring Internet Freedom
Order’’) in WC Docket No. 17–108,
adopted on December 14, 2017 and
released on January 4, 2018. The full
text of this document is available at
https://apps.fcc.gov/edocs_public/
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
SUMMARY:
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
attachmatch/FCC-17-166A1.pdf. The
full text is also available for public
inspection during regular business
hours in the FCC Reference Information
Center, Portals II, 445 12th Street SW,
Room CY–A257, Washington, DC 20554.
To request materials in accessible
formats for people with disabilities (e.g.,
braille, large print, electronic files,
audio format, etc.) or to request
reasonable accommodations (e.g.,
accessible format documents, sign
language interpreters, CART, etc.), send
an email to fcc504@fcc.gov or call the
Consumer & Governmental Affairs
Bureau at (202) 418–0530 (voice) or
(202) 418–0432 (TTY). The language
following the DATES caption of this
preamble is provided to ensure
compliance with 1 CFR 18.17.
Below, we find that economic theory,
empirical data, and even anecdotal
evidence also counsel against imposing
public-utility style regulation on ISPs.
The broader internet ecosystem thrived
under the light-touch regulatory
treatment of Title I, with massive
investment and innovation by both ISPs
and edge providers, leading to
previously unimagined technological
developments and services. We
conclude that a return to Title I
classification will facilitate critical
broadband investment and innovation
by removing regulatory uncertainty and
lowering compliance costs.
Synopsis
In this Declaratory Ruling, Report and
Order, and Order, the Commission
restores the light-touch regulatory
scheme that fostered the internet’s
growth, openness, and freedom.
Through these actions, we advance our
critical work to promote broadband
deployment in rural America and
infrastructure investment throughout
the nation, brighten the future of
innovation both within networks and at
their edge, and move closer to the goal
of eliminating the digital divide.
1. Scope
2. We continue to define ‘‘broadband
internet access service’’ as a massmarket retail service by wire or radio
that provides the capability to transmit
data to and receive data from all or
substantially all internet endpoints,
including any capabilities that are
incidental to and enable the operation of
the communications service, but
excluding dial-up internet access
service. By mass market, we mean
services marketed and sold on a
standardized basis to residential
customers, small businesses, and other
end-user customers such as schools and
libraries. ‘‘Schools’’ would include
institutions of higher education to the
extent that they purchase these
standardized retail services. For
purposes of this definition, ‘‘mass
market’’ also includes broadband
internet access service purchased with
the support of the E-rate and Rural
Healthcare programs, as well as any
broadband internet access service
offered using networks supported by the
Connect America Fund (CAF), but does
not include enterprise service offerings
or special access services, which are
typically offered to larger organizations
through customized or individually
negotiated arrangements.
3. The term ‘‘broadband internet
access service’’ includes services
provided over any technology platform,
including but not limited to wire,
terrestrial wireless (including fixed and
mobile wireless services using licensed
or unlicensed spectrum), and satellite.
For purposes of our discussion, we
divide the various forms of broadband
internet access service into the two
categories of ‘‘fixed’’ and ‘‘mobile.’’
With these two categories of services—
fixed and mobile—we intend to cover
the entire universe of internet access
services at issue in the Commission’s
I. Ending Public-Utility Regulation of
the Internet
1. We reinstate the information
service classification of broadband
internet access service, consistent with
the Supreme Court’s holding in Brand
X. Based on the record before us, we
conclude that the best reading of the
relevant definitional provisions of the
Act supports classifying broadband
internet access service as an information
service. Having determined that
broadband internet access service,
regardless of whether offered using
fixed or mobile technologies, is an
information service under the Act, we
also conclude that as an information
service, mobile broadband internet
access service should not be classified
as a commercial mobile service or its
functional equivalent. We find that it is
well within our legal authority to
classify broadband internet access
service as an information service, and
reclassification also comports with
applicable law governing agency
decisions to change course. While we
find our legal analysis sufficient on its
own to support an information service
classification of broadband internet
access service, strong public policy
considerations further weigh in favor of
an information service classification.
PO 00000
Frm 00002
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
A. Reinstating the Information Service
Classification of Broadband Internet
Access Service
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
prior broadband classification decisions,
as well as all other broadband internet
access services offered over other
technology platforms that were not
addressed by prior classification orders.
We also make clear that our
classification finding applies to all
providers of broadband internet access
service, as we delineate them here,
regardless of whether they lease or own
the facilities used to provide the service.
‘‘Fixed’’ broadband internet access
service refers to a broadband internet
access service that serves end users
primarily at fixed endpoints using
stationary equipment, such as the
modem that connects an end user’s
home router, computer, or other internet
access device to the internet. The term
encompasses the delivery of fixed
broadband over any medium, including
various forms of wired broadband
services (e.g., cable, DSL, fiber), fixed
wireless broadband services (including
fixed services using unlicensed
spectrum), and fixed satellite broadband
services. ‘‘Mobile’’ broadband internet
access service refers to a broadband
internet access service that serves end
users primarily using mobile stations.
Mobile broadband internet access
includes, among other things, services
that use smartphones or mobilenetwork-enabled tablets as the primary
endpoints for connection to the internet.
The term also encompasses mobile
satellite broadband services. We note
that ‘‘public safety services’’ as defined
in Section 337(f)(1) would not meet the
definition of ‘‘broadband internet access
service’’ subject to the rules herein
given that ‘‘such services are not made
commercially available to the public by
the provider’’ as a mass-market retail
service.
4. As the Commission found in 2010,
broadband internet access service does
not include services offering
connectivity to one or a small number
of internet endpoints for a particular
device, e.g., connectivity bundled with
e-readers, heart monitors, or energy
consumption sensors, to the extent the
service relates to the functionality of the
device. To the extent these services are
provided by ISPs over last-mile capacity
shared with broadband internet access
service, they would be non-broadband
internet access service data services
(formerly specialized services). As the
Commission found in both 2010 and
2015, non-broadband internet access
service data services do not fall under
the broadband internet access service
category. Such services generally are not
used to reach large parts of the internet;
are not a generic platform, but rather a
specific applications-level service; and
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
use some form of network management
to isolate the capacity used by these
services from that used by broadband
internet access services. Further, we
observe that to the extent ISPs ‘‘use their
broadband infrastructure to provide
video and voice services, those services
are regulated in their own right.’’
5. Broadband internet access service
also does not include virtual private
network (VPN) services, content
delivery networks (CDNs), hosting or
data storage services, or internet
backbone services (if those services are
separate from broadband internet access
service), consistent with past
Commission precedent. The
Commission has historically
distinguished these services from ‘‘mass
market’’ services, as they do not provide
the capability to transmit data to and
receive data from all or substantially all
internet endpoints. We do not disturb
that finding here. Consistent with past
Commissions, we note that the
transparency rule we adopt today
applies only so far as the limits of an
ISP’s control over the transmission of
data to or from its broadband customers.
6. Finally, we observe that to the
extent that coffee shops, bookstores,
airlines, private end-user networks such
as libraries and universities, and other
businesses acquire broadband internet
access service from an ISP to enable
patrons to access the internet from their
respective establishments, provision of
such service by the premise operator
would not itself be considered a
broadband internet access service unless
it was offered to patrons as a retail mass
market service, as we define it here.
Although not bound by the transparency
rule we adopt today, we encourage
premise operators to disclose relevant
restrictions on broadband service they
make available to their patrons.
Likewise, when a user employs, for
example, a wireless router or a Wi-Fi
hotspot to create a personal Wi-Fi
network that is not intentionally offered
for the benefit of others, he or she is not
offering a broadband internet access
service under our definition, because
the user is not marketing and selling
such service to residential customers,
small business, and other end-user
customers such as schools and libraries.
2. Broadband Internet Access Service is
an Information Service Under the Act
7. In deciding how to classify
broadband internet access service, we
find that the best reading of the relevant
definitional provisions of the Act
supports classifying broadband internet
access service as an information service.
Section 3 of the Act defines an
‘‘information service’’ as ‘‘the offering of
PO 00000
Frm 00003
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
7853
a capability for generating, acquiring,
storing, transforming, processing,
retrieving, utilizing, or making available
information via telecommunications,
and includes electronic publishing, but
does not include any use of any such
capability for the management, control,
or operation of a telecommunications
system or the management of a
telecommunications service.’’ Section 3
defines a ‘‘telecommunications service,’’
by contrast, as ‘‘the offering of
telecommunications for a fee directly to
the public, or to such classes of users as
to be effectively available directly to the
public, regardless of the facilities used.’’
Finally, Section 3 defines
‘‘telecommunications’’—used in each of
the prior two definitions—as ‘‘the
transmission, between or among points
specified by the user, of information of
the user’s choosing, without change in
the form or content of the information
as sent and received.’’ Prior to the Title
II Order the Commission had long
interpreted and applied these terms to
classify various forms of internet access
service as information services—a
conclusion affirmed as reasonable by
the Supreme Court in Brand X. Our
action here simply returns to that prior
approach.
8. When interpreting a statute it
administers, the Commission, like all
agencies, ‘‘must operate ‘within the
bounds of reasonable interpretation.’
And reasonable statutory interpretation
must account for both ‘the specific
context in which . . . language is used’
and ‘the broader context of the statute
as a whole.’ ’’ Below, we first explore
the meaning of the ‘‘capability’’
contemplated in the statutory definition
of ‘‘information service,’’ and find that
broadband internet access service
provides consumers the ‘‘capability’’ to
engage in all of the information
processes listed in the information
service definition. We also find that
broadband internet access service
likewise provides information
processing functionalities itself, such as
DNS and caching, which satisfy the
capabilities set forth in the information
service definition. We then address
what ‘‘capabilities’’ we believe are being
‘‘offered’’ by ISPs, and whether these are
reasonably viewed as separate from or
inextricably intertwined with
transmission, and find that broadband
internet access service offerings
inextricably intertwine these
information processing capabilities with
transmission.
9. We find that applying our
understanding of the statutory
definitions to broadband internet access
service as it is offered today most
soundly leads to the conclusion that it
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
7854
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
is an information service. Although the
internet marketplace has continued to
develop in the years since the earliest
classification decisions, broadband
internet access service offerings still
involve a number of ‘‘capabilities’’
within the meaning of the Section 3
definition of information services,
including critical capabilities that all
ISP customers must use for the service
to work as it does today. While many
popular uses of the internet have shifted
over time, the record reveals that
broadband internet access service
continues to offer information service
capabilities that typical users both
expect and rely upon. Indeed, the basic
nature of internet service—
‘‘[p]rovid[ing] consumers with a
comprehensive capability for
manipulating information using the
internet via high-speed
telecommunications’’—has remained
the same since the Supreme Court
upheld the Commission’s similar
classification of cable modem service as
an information service twelve years ago.
10. A body of precedent from the
courts and the Commission served as
the backdrop for the 1996 Act and
informed the Commission’s original
interpretation and implementation of
the statutory definitions of
‘‘telecommunications,’’
‘‘telecommunications service,’’ and
‘‘information service.’’ The
classification decisions in the Title II
Order discounted or ignored much of
that precedent. Without viewing
ourselves as formally bound by that
prior precedent, we find it eminently
reasonable, as a legal matter, to give
significant weight to that pre-1996 Act
precedent in resolving how the statutory
definitions apply to broadband internet
access service, enabling us to resolve
statutory ambiguity in a manner that we
believe best reflects Congress’s
understanding and intent. Our analysis
thus is not at odds with the statement
in USTelecom that the 1996 Act
definitions were not ‘‘intended to freeze
in place the Commission’s existing
classification of various services.’’
Consistent with this approach as a
traditional tool of statutory
interpretation, we reject arguments that
suggest that we should disregard this
precedent largely out-of-hand. More
generally, of course, this precedent—
Brand X in particular—demonstrates
that the Act does not compel a
telecommunications service
classification.
a. Broadband Internet Access Service
Information Processing Capabilities
11. We begin by evaluating the
‘‘information service’’ definition and
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
conclude that it encompasses broadband
internet access service. Broadband
internet access service includes
‘‘capabilit[ies]’’ meeting the information
service definition under a range of
reasonable interpretations of that term.
In other contexts, the Commission has
looked to dictionary definitions and
found the term ‘‘capability’’ to be
‘‘broad and expansive,’’ including the
concepts of ‘‘potential ability’’ and ‘‘the
capacity to be used, treated, or
developed for a particular purpose.’’
Because broadband internet access
service necessarily has the capacity or
potential ability to be used to engage in
the activities within the information
service definition—‘‘generating,
acquiring, storing, transforming,
processing, retrieving, utilizing, or
making available information via
telecommunications’’—we conclude
that it is best understood to have those
‘‘capabilit[ies].’’ The record reflects that
fundamental purposes of broadband
internet access service are for its use in
‘‘generating’’ and ‘‘making available’’
information to others, for example
through social media and file sharing;
‘‘acquiring’’ and ‘‘retrieving’’
information from sources such as
websites and online streaming and
audio applications, gaming applications,
and file sharing applications; ‘‘storing’’
information in the cloud and remote
servers, and via file sharing
applications; ‘‘transforming’’ and
‘‘processing’’ information such as by
manipulating images and documents,
online gaming use, and through
applications that offer the ability to send
and receive email, cloud computing and
machine learning capabilities; and
‘‘utilizing’’ information by interacting
with stored data. These are just a few
examples of how broadband internet
access service enables customers to
generate, acquire, store, transform,
process, retrieve, utilize, and make
available information. These are not
merely incidental uses of broadband
internet access service—rather, because
it not only has ‘‘the capacity to be used’’
for these ‘‘particular purpose[s]’’ but
was designed and intended to do so, we
find that broadband internet access is
best interpreted as providing customers
with the ‘‘capability’’ for such
interactions with third party providers.
12. We also find that broadband
internet access is an information service
irrespective of whether it provides the
entirety of any end user functionality or
whether it provides end user
functionality in tandem with edge
providers. We do not believe that
Congress, in focusing on the ‘‘offering of
a capability,’’ intended the classification
PO 00000
Frm 00004
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
question to turn on an analysis of which
capabilities the end user selects.
Further, we are unpersuaded by
commenters who assert that in order to
be considered an ‘‘information service,’’
an ISP must not only offer customers the
‘‘capability’’ for interacting with
information that may be offered by third
parties (‘‘click-through’’), but must also
provide the ultimate content and
applications themselves. Although there
is no dispute that many edge providers
likewise perform functions to facilitate
information processing capabilities,
they all depend on the combination of
information-processing and
transmission that ISPs make available
through broadband internet access
service. The fundamental purpose of
broadband internet access service is to
‘‘enable a constant flow of computermediated communications between enduser devices and various servers and
routers to facilitate interaction with
online content.’’
13. From the earliest decisions
classifying internet access service, the
Commission recognized that even when
ISPs enable subscribers to access third
party content and services, that can
constitute ‘‘a capability for generating,
acquiring, storing, transforming,
processing, retrieving, utilizing, or
making available information via
telecommunications.’’ As the
Commission explained in the Stevens
Report, ‘‘[s]ubscribers can retrieve files
from the World Wide Web, and browse
their contents, because their service
provider offers the ‘capability for . . .
acquiring, . . . retrieving [and] utilizing
. . . information.’ ’’ Attempts to
distinguish the Commission’s
classification precedent thus are
unfounded insofar as they fail to
account for this aspect of the
Commission’s analysis in those orders.
Thus, even where an ISP enables endusers to access the content or
applications of a third party, the
Commission nonetheless found that
constituted the requisite information
service ‘‘capability.’’ When the Title II
Order attempted to evaluate customer
perception based on their usage of
broadband internet access service, it
failed to persuasively grapple with the
relevant implications of prior
Commission classification precedent.
The Title II Order argued that broadband
internet access service primarily is used
to access content, applications, and
services from third parties unaffiliated
with the ISP in support of the view that
customers perceive it as a separate
offering of telecommunications. The
Title II Order offers no explanation as to
why its narrower view of ‘‘capability’’
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
was more reasonable than the
Commission’s previous, long-standing
view (other than seeking to advance the
classification outcome that Order was
driving towards). Consequently, the
Title II Order essentially assumed away
the legal question of whether end-users
perceive broadband internet access
service as offering them the ‘‘capability
for . . . acquiring, . . . retrieving [and]
utilizing . . . information’’ under the
broader reading of ‘‘capability’’ in prior
Commission precedent.
14. But even if ‘‘capability’’ were
understood as requiring more of the
information processing to be performed
by the classified service itself, we find
that broadband internet access service
meets that standard. Not only do ISPs
offer end users the capability to interact
with information online in each and
every one of the ways set forth above,
they also do so through a variety of
functionally integrated information
processing components that are part and
parcel of the broadband internet access
service offering itself. In particular, we
conclude that DNS and caching
functionalities, as well as certain other
information processing capabilities
offered by ISPs, are integrated
information processing capabilities
offered as part of broadband internet
access service to consumers today. In
addition to DNS and caching, the record
reflects that ISPs may also offer a variety
of additional features that consist of
information processing functionality
inextricably intertwined with the
underlying service. These additional
features include, and are not limited to:
email, speed test servers, backup and
support services, geolocation-based
advertising, data storage, parental
controls, unique programming content,
spam protection, pop-up blockers,
instant messaging services, on-the-go
access to Wi-Fi hotspots, and various
widgets, toolbars, and applications.
While we do not find the offering of
these information processing
capabilities determinative of the
classification of broadband internet
access service, their inclusion in the
broadband internet access service, and
the capabilities and functionalities
necessary to make these features
possible, further support the
‘‘information service’’ classification.
15. DNS. We find that DNS is an
indispensable functionality of
broadband internet access service.
While we accept that DNS is not
necessary for transmission, we reject
assertions that it is not indispensable to
the broadband internet access service
customers use—and expect—today.
DNS is a core function of broadband
internet access service that involves the
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
capabilities of generating, acquiring,
storing, transforming, processing,
retrieving, utilizing and making
available information. DNS is used to
facilitate the information retrieval
capabilities that are inherent in internet
access. DNS allows ‘‘‘click through’
access from one web page to another,
and its computer processing functions
analyze user queries to determine which
website (and server) would respond best
to the user’s request.’’ And ‘‘[b]ecause it
translates human language (e.g., the
name of a website) into the numerical
data (i.e., an IP address) that computers
can process, it is indispensable to
ordinary users as they navigate the
internet.’’ Without DNS, a consumer
would not be able to access a website by
typing its advertised name (e.g., fcc.gov
or cnn.com). The Brand X Court
recognized the importance of DNS,
concluding that ‘‘[f]or an internet user,
‘DNS is a must. . . . [N]early all of the
internet’s network services use DNS.
That includes the World Wide Web,
electronic mail, remote terminal access,
and file transfer.’ ’’ While ISPs are not
the sole providers of DNS services, the
vast majority of ordinary consumers rely
upon the DNS functionality provided by
their ISP, and the absence of ISPprovided DNS would fundamentally
change the online experience for the
consumer. We also observe that DNS, as
it is used today, provides more than a
functionally integrated addresstranslation capability, but also enables
other capabilities critical to providing a
functional broadband internet access
service to the consumer, including for
example, a variety of underlying
network functionality information
associated with name service,
alternative routing mechanisms, and
information distribution.
16. The treatment of similar functions
in MFJ precedent bolsters our
conclusion. Despite the fact that the
telecommunications management
exception (and information service
definition more broadly) was drawn
most directly from the MFJ, the Title II
Order essentially ignored MFJ precedent
when concluding that DNS fell within
the statutory telecommunications
management exception. In addition,
even the Title II Order’s limited use of
Computer Inquiries precedent focused
mostly on relatively high-level
Commission statements about the
general sorts of capabilities that could
be basic (or adjunct-to-basic) or drew
analogies to specific holdings that are at
best ambiguous as to their application to
broadband internet access service.
When analyzing ‘‘gateway’’
functionalities by which BOCs would
PO 00000
Frm 00005
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
7855
provide end-users with access to third
party information services, the MFJ
court found that ‘‘address translation,’’
which enabled ‘‘the consumer [to] use
an abbreviated code or signal . . . in
order to access the information service
provider’’ such as through ‘‘the
translation of a mnemonic code into [a]
telephone number,’’ rendered gateways
an information service. We recognize
that gateway functionalities and
broadband internet access service are
not precisely coextensive in scope. We
do, however, find similarities between
functionalities such as address
translation and storage and retrieval to
key functionalities provided by ISPs as
part of broadband internet access
service, and we conclude the court
found such gateway and similar
functionalities independently sufficient
to warrant an information service
classification under the MFJ. The
‘‘address translation’’ gateway function
appears highly analogous to the DNS
function of broadband internet access
service, which enables end users to use
easier-to-remember domain names to
initiate access to the associated IP
addresses of edge providers. That MFJ
precedent, neglected by the Title II
Order, thus supports our finding that
the inclusion of DNS in broadband
internet access service offerings likewise
renders that service an information
service. We rely on this analogy
between DNS and particular functions
classified under pre-1996 Act precedent
not because the technologies are
identical in all particulars, but because
they share the same relevant
characteristics for purposes of making a
classification decision under the Act.
Given the close fit between DNS and the
address translation function classified
as an information service under the MFJ
coupled with the fact that the statutory
information service definition (and
telecommunications management
exception) was drawn more directly
from the MFJ, we find the MFJ
precedent entitled to more weight than
analogies to Computer Inquiries
precedent. We thus are not persuaded
by arguments seeking to analogize DNS
to directory assistance, which the
Commission classified as ‘‘adjunct-tobasic’’ under the Computer Inquiries.
17. We thus find that the Title II Order
erred in finding that DNS functionalities
fell within the telecommunications
systems management exception to the
definition of ‘‘information service.’’
That exception from the statutory
information service definition was
drawn from the language of the MFJ,
and was understood as ‘‘directed at
internal operations, not at services for
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
7856
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
customers or end users.’’ The court’s
definition of information services
excluded capabilities ‘‘for the
management, control, or operation of a
telecommunication system or the
management of a telecommunications
service.’’ Under the Communications
Act, the definition of ‘‘information
services’’ includes an identicallyworded ‘‘telecommunications
management’’ exception. Commission
precedent and legislative history
likewise recognize that the definition
was drawn from the MFJ. We interpret
the concepts of ‘‘management, control,
or operation’’ in the
telecommunications management
exception consistent with that
understanding. Applying that
interpretation, we find the record
reflects that little or nothing in the DNS
look-up process is designed to help an
ISP ‘‘manage’’ its network; instead, DNS
functionalities ‘‘provide stored
information to end users to help them
navigate the internet.’’ As AT&T
explains: ‘‘When an end user types a
domain name into his or her browser
and sends a DNS query to an ISP, . . .
the ISP . . . converts the humanlanguage domain name into a numerical
IP address, and it then conveys that
information back to the end user . . .
[who] (via his or her browser) thereafter
sends a follow-up request for the
internet resources located at that
numerical IP address.’’ DNS does not
merely ‘‘manage’’ a telecommunications
service, as some commenters assert, but
rather is a function that is useful and
essential to providing internet access for
the ordinary consumer. We are
persuaded that ‘‘[w]ere DNS simply a
management function, this would not be
the case.’’ Comparing functions that
would fall within the exception
illustrates the distinction. For example,
in contrast to DNS’s interaction with
users and their applications, ‘‘non-user,
management-only protocols might
include things such as Simple Network
Management Protocol (SNMP), Network
Control Protocol (NETCONF), or
DOCSIS bootfiles for controlling the
configuration of cable modems.’’ These
protocols support services that manage
the network independent of the
transmission of information initiated by
a user. Other functions that would fall
into the telecommunications systems
management exception might include
information systems for account
management and billing, configuration
management, and the monitoring of
failures and other state information, and
to keep track of which addresses are
reachable through each of the
interconnected neighboring networks.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
18. The Title II Order drew erroneous
conclusions from Computer Inquiries
precedent and too quickly rejected
objections to its treatment of DNS as
meeting the telecommunications
management exception. The same
shortcomings are present in the Title II
Order’s analysis of caching, as well.
Under the Computer Inquiries
framework, the Commission held that
some capabilities ‘‘may properly be
associated with basic [common carrier]
service without changing its nature, or
with an enhanced service without
changing the classification of the latter
as unregulated under Title II of the
Act.’’ These commonly came to be
known as ‘‘adjunct’’ capabilities. The
Commission has held that functions it
had classified as ‘‘adjunct-to-basic’’
under the Computer Inquiries
framework will fall within the statutory
telecommunications management
exception to the information service
definition. Drawing loose analogies to
certain functions described as adjunctto-basic under Commission precedent,
the Title II Order held that DNS fell
within the telecommunications
management exception.
19. The Title II Order incorrectly
assumed that so long as a functionality
was, in part, used in a manner that
could be viewed as adjunct-to-basic, it
necessarily was adjunct-to-basic
regardless of what the functionality
otherwise accomplished. In addition to
the MFJ precedent, Bureau precedent
similarly has observed that adjunct-tobasic capabilities do not include
functions ‘‘useful to end users, rather
than carriers.’’ Given the lack of
ambiguity in the MFJ’s holding in this
regard, we find it more reasonable to
interpret this precedent to call for a
similar requirement that ‘‘adjunct to
basic’’ services do not include services
primarily useful to end-users, and reject
arguments to the contrary. Although
confronted with claims that DNS is, in
significant part, designed to be useful to
end-users rather than providers, the
Title II Order nonetheless decided that
it fell within the telecommunications
management exception. The same is
true of the Title II Order’s treatment of
caching. While conceding that DNS, as
well as other functions like caching, ‘‘do
provide a benefit to subscribers,’’ the
Title II Order held that they nonetheless
fell within the telecommunications
management exception because it found
some aspect of their operation also was
of use to providers in managing their
networks. This expansive view of the
telecommunications management
exception—and associated narrowing of
the scope of information services—is a
PO 00000
Frm 00006
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
transposition of the analytical approach
embodied in the MFJ and Computer
Inquiries; under the approach in the pre1996 Act precedent, the analysis would
instead begin with the broad language of
the information service or enhanced
service definitions, generally excluding
particular functions only if the purpose
served clearly was narrowly focused on
facilitating bare transmission. The
Commission and the courts made clear
the narrow scope of the ‘adjunct-tobasic’ or ‘telecommunications
management’ categories in numerous
decisions in many different contexts.).
Notably, the focus remains on the
purpose or use of the specific function
in question and not merely whether the
resulting service, as a whole, is useful
to end-users.
20. The Title II Order also put
misplaced reliance on Computer
Inquiries adjunct-to-basic precedent
from the traditional telephone service
context as a comparison when
evaluating broadband internet access
service functionalities. Because
broadband internet access service was
not directly addressed in pre-1996 Act
Computer Inquiries and MFJ precedent,
analogies to functions that were
classified under that precedent must
account for potentially distinguishing
characteristics not only in terms of
technical details but also in terms of the
regulatory backdrop. The 1996 Act
enunciates a policy for the internet that
distinguishes broadband internet access
from legacy services like traditional
telephone service. The 1996 Act
explains that it is federal policy ‘‘to
preserve the vibrant and competitive
free market that presently exists for the
internet and other interactive computer
services, unfettered by Federal or State
regulation.’’ The application of
potentially ambiguous precedent to
broadband internet access service
should be informed by how well—or
how poorly—it advances that
deregulatory statutory policy. We find
that our approach to that precedent,
which results in an information service
classification of broadband internet
access service, better advances that
deregulatory policy than the approach
in the Title II Order, which led to the
imposition of utility-style regulation
under Title II.
21. The regulatory history of
traditional telephone service also
informs our understanding of Computer
Inquiries precedent, further
distinguishing it from broadband
internet access service. Given the long
history of common carriage offering of
that service by the time of the Computer
Inquiries, it is understandable that some
precedent started with a presumption
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
that the underlying service was a ‘‘basic
service.’’ But similar assumptions
would not be warranted in the case of
services other than traditional telephone
service for which there was no similar
longstanding history of common
carriage. Thus, not only did the Title II
Order rely on specific holdings that are
at best ambiguous in their analogy to
technical characteristics of broadband
internet access service, but it failed to
adequately appreciate key regulatory
distinctions between traditional
telephone service and broadband
internet access service. Thus, for
example, the fact that the adjunct-tobasic classification of directory
assistance arose in the traditional
telephone context likewise persuades us
to give it relatively little weight here as
an analogy to DNS, and we reject
arguments to the contrary.
22. Caching. We also conclude that
caching, a functionally integrated
information processing component of
broadband internet access service,
provides the capability to perform
functions that fall within the
information service definition. As the
record reflects, ‘‘[c]aching does much
more than simply enable the user to
obtain more rapid retrieval of
information through the network;
caching depends on complex algorithms
to determine what information to store
where and in what format.’’ This
requires ‘‘extensive information
processing, storing, retrieving, and
transforming for much of the most
popular content on the internet,’’ and as
such, caching involves storing and
retrieving capabilities required by the
‘‘information service’’ definition. The
Court affirmed this view in Brand X,
finding ‘‘reasonable’’ the ‘‘Commission’s
understanding’’ that internet service
‘‘facilitates access to third-party web
pages by offering consumers the ability
to store, or ‘cache,’ popular content on
local computer servers,’’ which
constitutes ‘‘the ‘capability for . . .
acquiring, [storing] . . . retrieving [and]
utilizing information.’ ’’
23. We find that ISP-provided caching
does not merely ‘‘manage’’ an ISP’s
broadband internet access service and
underlying network, it enables and
enhances consumers’ access to and use
of information online. The record shows
that caching can be realized as part of
a service, such as DNS, which is
predominantly to the benefit of the user
(DNS caching). We disagree with
assertions in the record that suggest that
ISP-provided caching is not a vital part
of broadband internet access service
offerings, as it may be stymied by the
use of HTTPS encryption. Caching can
also be realized in terms of content that
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
can be accumulated by the ISP through
non-confidential (i.e., non-encrypted)
retrieval of information from websites
(Web caching). In this case, the user
benefits from a rapid retrieval of
information from a local cache or
repository of information while the ISP
benefits from less bandwidth resources
used in the retrieval of data from one or
more destinations. DNS and Web
caching are functions provided as part
and parcel of the broadband internet
access service. When ISPs cache content
from across the internet, they are not
performing functions, like switching,
that are instrumental to pure
transmission, but instead storing third
party content they select in servers in
their own networks to enhance access to
information. The record reflects that
without caching, broadband internet
access service would be a significantly
inferior experience for the consumer,
particularly for customers in remote
areas, requiring additional time and
network capacity for retrieval of
information from the internet. Thus,
because caching is useful to the
consumer, we conclude that the Title II
Order erred in incorrectly categorizing
caching as falling within the
telecommunications system
management exception to the definition
of ‘‘information service.’’
24. In addition, the Title II Order’s
failure to consider applicable MFJ
precedent led to mistaken analogies
when it concluded that caching fell
within the statutory
telecommunications management
exception. In relevant precedent, the
MFJ court observed that the information
service restriction generally ‘‘prohibits
the [BOCs] from ‘storing’ and ‘retrieving’
information,’’ but identified ‘‘quite
distinct settings in which storage
capabilities of the [BOCs] could be used
in the information services market.’’
One of the categories of storage and
retrieval identified by the court appears
highly comparable to caching. That
category involved BOC provision of
‘‘storage space in their gateways for
databases created by others’’ such as
‘‘information service providers and end
users,’’ making ‘‘communication more
efficient by moving information closer
to the end user, thereby reducing
transmission costs.’’ This
functionality—recognized as an
information service by the MFJ court—
appears highly analogous to caching,
and lends historical support to our view
that the caching functionality within
broadband internet access service is best
understood as rendering broadband
internet access service an information
service. The first category the court
PO 00000
Frm 00007
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
7857
identified was ‘‘very short term
storage,’’ including, among other things,
‘‘the basic packet switching function,’’
which ‘‘involves the breakdown of data
or voice communications into small bits
of information that are then collected
and transmitted between nodes,’’
involving ‘‘constant storage, error
checking, and retransmission, as
required for accurate transmission.’’
Although the court was not entirely
clear, it seemed to suggest that such
functions were not information services
under the MFJ. This category appears to
bear little similarity to caching,
however. The third category of ‘‘storage
and retrieval’’ information service
functions identified by the court would
include the BOC’s provision of ‘‘voice
messaging, voice storage and retrieval,
and electronic mail.’’ Because that
category does not appear as analogous to
caching as the category identified by the
court and described above, nor was it
relied upon in the Title II Order’s
discussion of caching, we do not focus
on that third category in our discussion
here.
25. Ignoring that MFJ precedent, the
Title II Order erred in seeking to
analogize caching to ‘‘ ‘store and
forward technology [used] in routing
messages through the network as part of
a basic service’ ’’ mentioned in the
Computer II Final Decision. In fact,
consistent with the MFJ court’s
identification of distinct uses of storage
and forwarding, the cited portion of the
Computer II Final Decision recognized
that ‘‘the kind of enhanced store and
forward services that can be offered are
many and varied.’’ In that regard, the
Computer II Final Decision
distinguished ‘‘[t]he offering of store
and forward services’’ from ‘‘store and
forward technology,’’ explaining that
‘‘[m]essage or packet switching, for
example, is a store and forward
technology that may be employed in
providing basic service.’’ Reading that
discussion in full context and in
harmony with subsequent MFJ
precedent, the reference in the
Computer II Final Decision to ‘‘store and
forward technology’’ appears better
understood as mirroring a category of
storage and retrieval of information that
the MFJ court suggested was not an
information service—in particular, ‘‘the
basic packet switching function, . . .
[which] involves the breakdown of data
or voice communications into small bits
of information that are then collected
and transmitted between nodes.’’ That
category of activity relied upon in the
Title II Order thus actually appears to be
barely or not at all analogous to caching.
We instead find more persuasive the
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
7858
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
MFJ court’s information service
treatment of BOC provision of ‘‘storage
space in their gateways for databases
created by others’’ such as ‘‘information
service providers and end users’’—a
distinct category of storage and retrieval
functionality that is a close fit to
caching. We are unpersuaded by claims
that this MFJ precedent only is
analogous to CDNs and not ‘‘transparent
caching’’ based on asserted differences
in how it is determined what content
will be stored in each scenario.
Although the factual scenario discussed
in the MFJ anticipated end-users or
information service providers electing
what information to store, and that fact
may have partially informed the court’s
decision whether to ultimately allow
BOCs to provide that capability
notwithstanding its classification as an
information service, we do not read the
underlying classification as turning on
that issue. Further, in addition to the
distinctions between caching and storeand-forward technology acknowledged
even in this filing, Peha Dec. 7, 2017 Ex
Parte Letter at 4, we find additional
shortcomings in how the Title II Order
relied on adjunct-to-basic precedent.
b. ISPs’ Service Offerings Inextricably
Intertwine Information Processing
Capabilities With Transmission
26. Having established that broadband
internet access service has the
information processing capabilities
outlined in the definition of
‘‘information service,’’ the relevant
inquiry is whether ISPs’ broadband
internet access service offerings make
available information processing
technology inextricably intertwined
with transmission. Below we examine
both how consumers perceive the offer
of broadband internet access service, as
well as the nature of the service actually
offered by ISPs, and conclude that ISPs
are best understood as offering a service
that inextricably intertwines the
information processing capabilities
described above and transmission.
27. We begin by considering the
ordinary customer’s perception of the
ISP’s offer of broadband internet access
service. As Brand X explained, ‘‘[i]t is
common usage to describe what a
company ‘offers’ to a consumer as what
the consumer perceives to be the
integrated finished product.’’ ISPs
generally market and provide
information processing capabilities and
transmission capability together as a
single service. Therefore, it is not
surprising that consumers perceive the
offer of broadband internet access
service to include more than mere
transmission, and that customers want
and pay for functionalities that go
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
beyond mere transmission. As Cox
explains, ‘‘[w]hile consumers also place
significant weight on obtaining a
reliable and fast internet connection,
they view those attributes as a means of
enabling these capabilities to interact
with information online, not as ends in
and of themselves.’’ Indeed, record
evidence confirms that consumers
highly value the capabilities their ISPs
offer to acquire information from
websites, utilize information on the
internet, retrieve such information, and
otherwise process such information.
NHMC’s argument, based on what it
asserts to be a representative sample of
consumer complaints filed with the
Commission, is not persuasive. NHMC’s
methodology relied on Natural
Language Processing (NLP) to determine
words that co-occur in such complaints,
and then used ‘‘iterative clustering
algorithms’’ to ‘‘ma[p] connections
among them.’’ Neither NHMC’s
methodology nor the representative
extracts of the complaints NHMC
submitted demonstrate that individual
complaints about particular aspects of
service reflect how a customer would
perceive service offerings as a whole.
Indeed, the sample of complaints
attached by NHMC features a broad set
of issues, ranging widely from questions
about speed to ‘‘losing my internet
connection,’’ ‘‘charg[ing] extra for your
services,’’ ‘‘interrupt[ing] the service,’’
‘‘bully[ing] me into share plans,’’
‘‘Google arbitrarily engag[ing] in
monopolistic practices,’’ ‘‘charg[ing] me
modem rental fee,’’ or ‘‘basically no
technical support.’’ We further note that
to the extent that perceived speed is a
common complaint, that does not mean
consumers view broadband internet
access service as a pure transmission
service. A consumer’s perceived speed
for many activities (such as web
browsing) depends on informationprocessing elements of the service like
DNS and caching; indeed, caching’s
primary consumer benefit is allowing a
more rapid retrieval of information from
a local cache (increasing the perceived
speed of a consumer’s connection).
Moreover, the Commission has never
relied on such complaints to identify
what a service is. And for good reason:
We expect consumer complaints about
problems with a service—not every
aspect of it. Indeed, applying such a
methodology would lead to absurd
results: Should we redefine the public
switched network based on the millions
of robocall complaints we get each year
or the rural-call-completion problems
that we know are too prevalent? Of
course not.
PO 00000
Frm 00008
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
28. This view also accords with the
Commission’s historical understanding
that ‘‘[e]nd users subscribing to . . .
broadband internet access service
expect to receive (and pay for) a
finished, functionally integrated service
that provides access to the internet. End
users do not expect to receive (or pay
for) two distinct services—both internet
access service and a distinct
transmission service, for example.’’
While the Title II Order dwells at length
on the prominence of transmission
speed in ISP marketing, it makes no
effort to compare that emphasis to
historical practice. In fact, ISPs have
been highlighting transmission speed in
their marketing materials since long
before the Title II Order. The very first
report on advanced telecommunication
capability pursuant to Section 706(b) of
the 1996 Act, released in 1999, cited
ISPs’ marketing of their internet access
service speed. ISPs’ inclusion of speed
information in their marketing also was
acknowledged by the Court in Brand X,
which nonetheless upheld the
Commission’s information service
classification as reasonable. Indeed,
consideration of ISP marketing practices
has been part of the backdrop of all of
the Commission’s decisions classifying
broadband internet access service as an
information service and thus cannot
justify a departure from the historical
classification of broadband internet
access service as an information service.
29. The Title II Order’s reliance on ISP
marketing also assumes that it provides
a complete picture of what consumers
perceive as the finished product. First,
the record reflects that ISP marketing of
broadband encompasses features
beyond speed and reliability. Further,
because all broadband internet access
services rely on DNS and commonly
also rely on caching by ISPs, to the
extent that those capabilities, in
themselves, do not provide a point of
differentiation among services or
providers, it would be unsurprising that
ISPs did not feature them prominently
in their marketing or advertising,
particularly to audiences already
familiar with broadband internet access
service generally. Indeed, speed and
reliability are not exclusive to
telecommunications services; rather, the
record reflects that speed and reliability
are crucial attributes of an information
service. As such, we reject assertions
that speed and reliability are only
characteristics of telecommunications
services and further note that ISPs
market these aspects because they can
be differentiated, unlike DNS or
caching. Consequently, the mere fact
that broadband internet access service
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
marketing often focuses on
characteristics, such as transmission
speed, by which services and providers
can be differentiated sheds little to no
light on whether consumers perceive
broadband internet access service as
inextricably intertwining that data
transmission with information service
capabilities. Neither the discussion of
the consumer’s perspective by Justice
Scalia nor that in the Title II Order
identifies good reasons to depart from
the Commission’s prior understanding
that broadband internet access is a
single, integrated information service.
Justice Scalia contended that how
customers perceive cable modem
service is best understood by
considering the services for which it
would be a substitute—in his view at
the time, dial-up internet access and
digital subscriber line (DSL) service over
telephone networks. However, dial-up
internet access has substantially
diminished in marketplace significance
in the subsequent years. In addition, the
legal compulsion for facilities-based
carriers to offer broadband transmission
on a common carrier basis was
eliminated in 2005. Fixed and mobile
wireless broadband internet access
service have grown to play a much more
prominent role in the broadband
internet access service marketplace,
along with satellite broadband internet
access service, none of which ever was
under a legal compulsion to offer
broadband transmission on a common
carrier basis—nor, prior to the Title II
Order, were they interpreted as
voluntarily doing so. Consequently,
whatever might have been arguable at
the time of Brand X, the service
offerings in the marketplace as it
developed thereafter provide no reason
to expect that consumers ‘‘inevitabl[y]’’
would view broadband internet access
service as involving ‘‘both computing
functionality and the physical pipe’’ as
separate offerings based on comparisons
to the likely alternatives.
30. Separate and distinct from our
finding that an ISP ‘‘offers’’ an
information service from the consumer’s
perspective, we find that as a factual
matter, ISPs offer a single, inextricably
intertwined information service. The
record reflects that information
processes must be combined with
transmission in order for broadband
internet access service to work, and it is
the combined information processing
capabilities and transmission functions
that an ISP offers with broadband
internet access service. Thus, even
assuming that any individual consumer
could perceive an ISP’s offer of
broadband internet access service as
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
akin to a bare transmission service, the
information processing capabilities that
are actually offered as an integral part of
the service make broadband internet
access service an information service as
defined by the Act. As such, we reject
commenters’ assertions that the primary
function of ISPs is to simply transfer
packets and not process information.
31. The inquiry called for by the
relevant classification precedent focuses
on the nature of the service offering the
provider makes, rather than being
limited to the functions within that
offering that particular subscribers do,
in fact, use or that third parties also
provide. As the Commission recognized
in the Cable Modem Order, internet
access service was appropriately
classified as an offering of the
capabilities with the definition of an
information service ‘‘regardless of
whether subscribers use all of the
functions provided as part of the
service.’’ The Title II Order erroneously
contended that, because functions like
DNS and caching potentially could be
provided by entities other than the ISP
itself, those functions should not be
understood as part of a single, integrated
information service offered by ISPs.
However, the fact that some consumers
obtain these functionalities from thirdparty alternatives is not a basis for
ignoring the capabilities that a
broadband provider actually ‘‘offers.’’
The Title II Order gave no meaningful
explanation why a contrary, narrower
interpretation of ‘‘offer’’ was warranted
other than, implicitly, its seemingly
end-results driven effort to justify a
telecommunications service
classification of broadband internet
access service.
32. Our findings today are consistent
with classification precedent prior to
the Title II Order, which consistently
found that ISPs offer a single, integrated
service. Although we find the pre-1996
Act classification precedent relevant to
our classification of broadband internet
access service, we reject the view that
Congress would have expected
classification under the 1996 Act’s
statutory definitions to be tied to the
substantive common carrier
transmission requirements imposed
under those frameworks. We conclude
that the best view of the text and
structure of the Act undercuts
arguments that Congress sought to
preserve the substance of pre-1996 Act
regulations through the definitions it
adopted. Instead, where Congress
sought to address substantive
requirements akin to those in the MFJ
and Computer Inquiries, it did so by
adopting subjective obligations in the
1996 Act—even if not identical to the
PO 00000
Frm 00009
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
7859
pre-1996 Act requirements—and subject
to their own Congressionally specified
standards for when and to what entities
they apply. In addition, the wholesale
service focus of substantive MFJ and
Computer Inquiries common carrier
transmission obligations also
distinguishes them from the retail
service we classify here, likewise
undermining any claimed relevance of
those pre-1996 Act transmission
requirements to our classification
decision. The Commission recognized,
for example, that the transmission
underlying broadband internet access
required by the Computer Inquiries to be
offered on an unbundled, common
carrier basis and provided to ISPs was
not a ‘‘retail’’ service within the
meaning of Section 251(c)(4) resale
requirements. Nor did such a common
carrier transmission service itself enable
access to the internet, even if purchased
by end-users. By comparison, under the
Computer Inquiries, the finished service
offered to end-users relying on the
required common carrier transmission
as an input was regulated as an
enhanced service, not a common carrier
offering, even when offered by the
facilities-based carrier’s subsidiary.
Given our focus here on the finished
retail broadband internet access service,
we see little relevance to prior
regulatory requirements that were
imposed to ensure competing providers
had access to a wholesale input in the
form of a compelled common carriage
offering of bare transmission that did
not itself provide internet access. Even
the early classification analysis in the
Stevens Report recognized that ‘‘[i]n
offering service to end users’’ ISPs ‘‘do
more than resell [ ] data transport
services. They conjoin the data transport
with data processing, information
provision, and other computer-mediated
offerings, thereby creating an
information service.’’ In Brand X, the
Court rejected claims that ‘‘[w]hen a
consumer . . . accesses content
provided by parties other than the cable
company’’ that ‘‘consumer uses ‘pure
transmission.’ ’’ Subsequent
Commission decisions involving other
forms of broadband internet access
likewise all concluded that the
broadband internet access service was a
single, integrated service that did not
involve a stand-alone offering of
telecommunications. Although parties
have, over time, held various views
regarding the proper classification of
broadband internet access services, the
mere fact that a party held such a view
in the past, or holds such a view today,
does not render a Commission decision
confirming a particular view ‘‘moot,’’
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
7860
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
since a private party’s subjective view is
not authoritative. The Court further
found that ‘‘the high-speed transmission
used to provide cable modem service is
a functionally integrated component of
that service because it transmits data
only in connection with the further
processing of information and is
necessary to provide internet service.’’
This distinction makes broadband
internet access service fundamentally
different than standard telephone
service, which the Supreme Court noted
does not become an ‘‘information
service’’ merely because its transmission
service may be ‘‘trivially affected’’ by
some additional capability such as
voicemail. Where the addition of some
further capability has appeared to have
only a trivial effect on the nature of a
service, the Commission has previously
declined requests for reclassification.
Due to the functionally integrated
nature of broadband internet access
service, however, we reject claims that
those decisions call for a different
approach than we adopt here. Likewise,
the outcome in the Bureau-level Cisco
WebEx Order accords with our
approach, given the finding that the
information service capabilities more
than trivially affected the transmission
capability in the scenario addressed
there. Contrary to some arguments, the
Bureau had no need to—and did not—
address the classification of other
service scenarios, and we reject
arguments for a different classification
approach that are premised on
assumptions about how those
unaddressed scenarios would have been
analyzed or classified. The core,
essential elements of these prior
analyses of the functional nature of
internet access remain persuasive as to
broadband internet access service today.
We adhere to that view notwithstanding
arguments that some subset of the array
of internet access uses identified in the
Stevens Report or subsequent decisions
either are no longer as commonly used,
or occur more frequently today. Even at
the time of the Cable Modem Order the
Commission recognized the role of usergenerated content, and its decision in no
way hinged on distinctions in how retail
customers of cable modem service used
that service in that respect.
33. We disagree with commenters
who assert that ISPs necessarily offer
both an information service and a
telecommunications service because
broadband internet access service
includes a transmission component. In
providing broadband internet access
service, an ISP makes use of
telecommunications—i.e., it provides
information-processing capabilities ‘‘via
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
telecommunications’’—but does not
separately offer telecommunications on
a stand-alone basis to the public. By
definition, all information services
accomplish their functions ‘‘via
telecommunications,’’ and as such,
broadband internet access service has
always had a telecommunications
component intrinsically intertwined
with the computer processing,
information provision, and computer
interactivity capabilities an information
service offers. We observe that placing
information in IP packets does not
change the form of information. We find
that the transmission of IP packets is
transmission of the user’s choosing, and
also agree that ‘‘[c]hanging the packet
structure of an IP packet from IPv4 to
IPv6’’ does not change the form of the
information. As just one example, in
support of its classification decision, the
Title II Order notes that it is technically
possible for a transmission component
underlying broadband internet access
service to be separated out and offered
on a common carrier basis. The same
would be equally true of many
information services, however, given
that the information service capabilities
are, by definition, available ‘‘via
telecommunications.’’ Indeed, service
providers, who are in the best position
to understand the inputs used in
broadband internet access service, do
not appear to dispute that the ‘‘via
telecommunications’’ criteria is satisfied
even if also arguing that they are not
providing telecommunications to endusers. For example, ISPs typically
transmit traffic between aggregation
points on their network and the ISPs’
connections with other networks.
Whether self-provided by the ISP or
purchased from a third party, that
readily appears to be transmission
between or among points selected by the
ISP of traffic that the ISP has chosen to
have carried by that transmission link.
We reject as overbroad the claim that ‘‘a
transmission is ‘telecommunications’
within the meaning of 47 U.S.C. 153(30)
only if the transmission is capable of
communicating with all circuit
switched devices on the PSTN or has
the purpose of facilitating the use of the
PSTN without altering its fundamental
character as a telephone network.’’ This
claim appears premised on
incorporating Section 332’s definition of
a commercial mobile service (which
must be ‘‘interconnected’’ with the
‘‘public switched network’’) into
Section 3 of the Act and drawing from
pre-1996 Act precedent using an end-toend analysis to determine the regulatory
jurisdiction of communications traffic to
inform the interpretation of the term
PO 00000
Frm 00010
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
‘‘points.’’ But we find no evidence in
the text of the statute that Congress
intended to import the commercial
mobile service definition from one
section into another, and our precedent
similarly does not countenance such an
importation. Nor is the end-to-end
analysis the only pre-1996 Act
precedent from which the concept of
‘‘points’’ in the ‘‘telecommunications’’
definition might have been drawn so as
to unambiguously foreclose our
conclusion that ‘‘via
telecommunications’’ is satisfied here.
Such inclusion of a transmission
component does not render broadband
internet access services
telecommunications services; if it did,
the entire category of information
services would be narrowed drastically.
Because we find it more reasonable to
conclude that at least some
telecommunications is being used as an
input into broadband internet access
service—thereby satisfying the ‘‘via
telecommunications’’ criteria—we need
not further address the scope of the
‘‘telecommunications’’ definition in
order to justify our classification of
broadband internet access service as an
information service. We thus do not
comprehensively address other
criticisms of the Title II Order’s
interpretation and applications of the
‘‘telecommunications’’ definition,
which potentially could have
implications beyond the scope of issues
we are considering in this proceeding.
34. The approach we adopt today best
implements the Commission’s longstanding view that Congress intended
the definitions of ‘‘telecommunications
service’’ and ‘‘information service’’ to be
mutually exclusive ways to classify a
given service. As the Brand X Court
found, the term ‘‘offering’’ in the
telecommunications service definition
‘‘can reasonably be read to mean a
‘stand-alone’ offering of
telecommunications.’’ Where, as in the
case of broadband internet access
services, a service involving
transmission inextricably intertwines
that transmission with information
service capabilities—in the form of an
integrated information service—there
cannot be ‘‘a ‘stand-alone’ offering of
telecommunications’’ as required under
that interpretation of the
telecommunications service definition.
This conclusion is true even if the
information service could be said to
involve the provision of
telecommunications as a component of
the service. The Commission’s historical
approach to internet access services
carefully navigated that issue, while the
Title II Order, by contrast, threatened to
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
usher in a much more sweeping scope
of ‘‘telecommunications services.’’
35. The Title II Order interpretation
stands in stark contrast to the
Commission’s historical classification
precedent and the views of all Justices
in Brand X. Beginning with the earliest
classification decisions, the Commission
found that transmission provided by
ISPs outside the last mile was part of an
integrated information service. The DSL
transmission service previously
required to be unbundled by the
Computer Inquiries rules likewise was
limited to the ‘‘last mile’’ connection
between the end-user and the ISP. Nor
did any Justice in Brand X contest the
view that, beyond the last mile, cable
operators were offering an information
service. Indeed, the Title II Order’s
broad interpretation of
‘‘telecommunications service’’ stands in
contrast to the views of Justice Scalia
himself, on which the Title II Order
purports to rely. Justice Scalia was
skeptical that a telecommunications
service classification of cable modem
service would lead to the classification
of ISPs as telecommunications carriers
based on the transmission underlying
their ‘‘connect[ions] to other parts of the
internet, including internet backbone
providers.’’ Yet the Title II Order
reached essentially that outcome. The
Title II Order’s interpretation of the
statutory definitions did not merely lead
it to classify ‘‘last mile’’ transmission as
a telecommunications service. Rather,
under the view of the Title II Order,
even the transmissions underlying an
ISP’s connections to other parts of the
internet, including internet backbone
providers, were part of the classified
telecommunications service. Even if the
Title II Order’s classification approach
does not technically render the category
of information services a nullity, the fact
that its view of telecommunications
services sweeps so much more broadly
than previously considered possible
provides significant support for our
reading of the statute and the
classification decision we make today.
That the Commission previously
identified policy concerns about
internet traffic exchange says nothing
about classification, and thus is not to
the contrary. Nor did the Advanced
Services proceedings identify
interconnection obligations on
providers of xDSL transmission as
services necessary to ensure the
provision of internet access. Instead,
any interconnection obligations
identified there were limited to
interconnection between providers of
common carrier xDSL transmission
service and other telecommunications
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
carriers (rather than providers of edge
services or non-common carrier
backbone services). The cited portion of
the Advanced Services Remand Order
does not even have anything to do with
interconnection requirements or the
scope of functions in an xDSL-based
advanced service. Rather, it analyzed
the jurisdiction of the traffic being
carried over the service, which, under
the traditional end-to-end analysis, was
not limited in scope to any given service
within a broader communications
pathway.
36. In contrast, our approach leaves
ample room for a meaningful range of
‘‘telecommunications services.’’
Historically, the Commission has
distinguished service offerings that
‘‘always and necessarily combine’’
functions such as ‘‘computer processing,
information provision, and computer
interactivity with data transport,
enabling end users to run a variety of
applications such as email, and access
web pages and newsgroups,’’ on the one
hand, from services ‘‘that carriers and
end users typically use [ ] for basic
transmission purposes’’ on the other
hand. Our interpretation thus stops far
short of the view that ‘‘every
transmission of information becomes an
information service.’’ Thus, an offering
like broadband internet access service
that ‘‘always and necessarily’’ includes
integrated transmission and information
service capabilities would be an
information service. The distinction
between services that ‘‘always and
necessarily’’ include integrated
transmission and information service
capabilities and those that do not also
highlights a critical difference between
internet access service and the service
addressed in precedent such as the
Advanced Services Order. The
transmission underlying internet access
service that, prior to the Wireline
Broadband Classification Order, carriers
had been required by the Computer
Inquiries to unbundle and offer as a bare
transmission service on a common
carrier basis to ensure its availability to
competing enhanced service
providers—and which did not itself
provide internet access—is another
specific example of a service that does
not ‘‘always and necessarily’’ include
integrated transmission and information
service capabilities. The Commission
naturally recognized at the time that the
compelled common carriage offering of
bare transmission was a
telecommunications service, and we
reject the view that such an
acknowledgment is inconsistent with, or
undercuts our reliance on, precedent
classifying internet access service as an
PO 00000
Frm 00011
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
7861
integrated information service. In
addition, the discussion of xDSL
advanced services in the Advanced
Services Order cited by commenters
addressed the transmission service
generally. It did not purport to be
focused specifically on the use of xDSL
transmission in connection with
internet access service, rather than
addressing the classification of the
stand-alone transmission service as a
general matter. The Commission’s
historical interpretation thus gives full
meaning to both ‘‘information service’’
and ‘‘telecommunications service’’
categories in the Act.
37. We reject assertions that the
analysis we adopt today would
necessarily mean that standard
telephone service is likewise an
information service. The record reflects
that broadband internet access service is
categorically different from standard
telephone service in that it is ‘‘designed
with advanced features, protocols, and
security measures so that it can integrate
directly into electronic computer
systems and enable users to
electronically create, retrieve, modify
and otherwise manipulate information
stored on servers around the world.’’
Further, ‘‘[t]he dynamic network
functionality enabling the internet
connectivity provided by [broadband
internet access services] is
fundamentally different from the largely
static one dimensional, transmission
oriented Time Division Multiplexing
(TDM) voice network.’’ This finding is
consistent with past distinctions. Under
pre-1996 Act MFJ precedent, for
example, although the provision of time
and weather services was an
information service, when a BOC’s
traditional telephone service was used
to call a third party time and weather
service ‘‘the Operating Company does
not ‘provide information services’
within the meaning of section II(D) of
the decree; it merely transmits a call
under the tariff.’’ In other words, the
fundamental nature of traditional
telephone service, and the commonlyunderstood purpose for which
traditional telephone service is designed
and offered, is to provide basic
transmission—a fact not changed by its
incidental use, on occasion, to access
information services. By contrast, the
fundamental nature of broadband
internet access service, and the
commonly-understood purpose for
which broadband internet access service
is designed and offered, is to enable
customers to generate, acquire, store,
transform, process, retrieve, utilize, and
make available information. In addition,
broadband internet access service
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
7862
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
includes DNS and caching
functionalities, as well as certain other
information processing capabilities. As
such, we reject assertions that, under
the approach we adopt today, any
telephone service would be an
information service because voice
customers can get access to either
automated information services or a live
person who can provide information.
38. Additionally, efforts to treat the
Stevens Report as an outlier that should
not have been followed in subsequent
classification decisions—and should not
be followed here—are ultimately
unpersuasive. The clear recognition in
the Stevens Report that the ISPs at issue
were themselves providing data
transmission as part of their offerings
undercuts arguments seeking to
distinguish the Stevens Report based on
the theory that the transmission used to
connect to ISPs typically involved
common carrier services either directly
(via a call to a dial-up ISP using
traditional telephone service) or
indirectly (with the ISP using common
carrier broadband transmission as a
wholesale input into its retail
information service). While the extent of
data transmission provided by the ISPs
that were found to be offering
information services in the Stevens
Report might be incrementally less than
the transmission provided by the ISPs
dealt with in subsequent information
service classification decisions, that
appears to be at most a difference in
degree, rather than a difference in kind,
and the record does not demonstrate
otherwise. Nor can the Stevens Report’s
analysis and information service
classification be distinguished on the
grounds that the ISPs there generally
did not own the facilities they used.
Although the Stevens Report observed
that the analysis of whether a single
integrated service was being offered was
‘‘more complicated when it comes to
offerings by facilities-based providers,’’
it did not prejudge the resolution of that
question. Thus, there is no reason to
simply assume that it was inappropriate
for the Commission to build upon the
Stevens Report precedent when
analyzing service offerings from
facilities-based providers beginning in
the Cable Modem Order. Nor do
commenters identify material technical
differences when facilities ownership is
involved that would mandate a different
classification analysis. While the
Stevens Report recognized that under
Computer Inquires precedent ‘‘offerings
by non-facilities-based providers
combining communications and
computing components should always
be deemed enhanced,’’ had its analysis
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
simply been carrying forward that
approach most of its analysis would
have been unnecessary (since internet
access clearly did combine
communications and computing
components). Thus, whether or not the
more extensive analysis set forth in the
Stevens Report was necessary to find
internet access provided by nonfacilities-based ISPs to be an
information service, that analysis cannot
be said to be a mere relic of the
Computer Inquiries approach to nonfacilities based providers. Finally, our
reliance on classification precedent does
not rest on the Stevens Report alone, but
draws from the full range of
classification precedent, both pre- and
post-1996 Act. This reliance notably
includes not only the Commission’s
classification decisions, but the
Supreme Court’s subsequent analysis in
Brand X. And although some
commenters criticize the lack of express
consideration of the possible
application of the telecommunications
management exception in the Stevens
Report, our evaluation of the pre-1996
Act MFJ and Computer Inquiries
precedent better accords with outcome
of that Report and the subsequent
classification decisions than it does
with the Title II Order in that regard. We
reject similar criticisms of other
precedent for the same reason.
3. Other Provisions of the Act Support
Broadband’s Information Service
Classification
39. We also find that other provisions
of the Act support our conclusion that
broadband internet access service is best
classified as an information service. We
do not assert that the language in
Sections 230 and 231 is determinative of
the information service classification;
rather, we find it to be supportive of our
analysis of the textual provisions at
issue. As such, we find Public
Knowledge’s assertions that the
Commission’s reasoning ‘‘would
overrule the Supreme Court’s holding in
Brand X . . . [in which] the Court ruled
that the Communications Act does not
make explicit the correct classification
of BIAS’’ inapposite. For instance,
Congress codified its view in Section
230(b)(2) of the Act, stating that it is the
policy of the United States ‘‘to preserve
the vibrant and competitive free market
that presently exists for the internet and
other interactive computer services,
unfettered by Federal or State
regulation.’’ This statement confirms
that the free market approach that flows
from classification as an information
service is consistent with Congress’s
intent. In contrast, we find it hard to
reconcile this statement in Section
PO 00000
Frm 00012
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
230(b)(2) with a conclusion that
Congress intended the Commission to
subject broadband internet access
service to common carrier regulation
under Title II.
40. Additional provisions within
Sections 230 and 231 of the Act lend
further support to our interpretation.
Section 230(f)(2) defines an interactive
computer service to mean ‘‘any
information service, system, or access
software provider that provides or
enables computer access by multiple
users to a computer server, including
specifically a service or system that
provides access to the Internet and such
systems operated or services offered by
libraries or educational institutions.’’
Thus, on its face, the plain language of
this provision appears to reflect
Congress’ judgment that internet access
service is an information service.
41. Section 230 states that an
‘‘information service’’ includes ‘‘a
service or system that provides access to
the internet,’’ and we disagree with
commenters who read the definition of
‘‘interactive computer service’’
differently. Specifically, we disagree
with commenters asserting that it is
unclear whether the clause ‘‘including
specifically a service . . . that provides
access to the internet’’ modifies
‘‘information service’’ or some other
noun phrase, such as ‘‘access software
provider’’ or ‘‘system.’’ We think it a
more reasonable interpretation that the
phrase ‘‘service . . . that provides
access to the internet’’ modifies the
noun phrase ‘‘information service.’’
Similarly, we disagree that Section
230(f)(2) proves only ‘‘that there exist
information services that provide access
to the internet, not that all services that
provide access to the internet are
information services.’’ On the contrary,
we agree with AT&T that ‘‘the formula
‘any X, including specifically a Y,’ does
logically imply that all Ys are Xs.’’
42. Reliance on Section 230(f)(2) to
inform the Commission’s interpretations
and applications of Titles I and II
accords with widely accepted canons of
statutory interpretation. The Supreme
Court has recognized there is a ‘‘natural
presumption that identical words used
in different parts of the same act are
intended to have the same meaning.’’
And there is nothing in the context of
either section that overcomes the
presumption. Indeed, the similarity of
circumstances confirms the
presumption of similar meaning, as the
deregulatory approach to information
services embodied in Titles I and II, as
well as the deregulatory policy of
Section 230, were all adopted as part of
the 1996 Act. Thus, we disagree with
the Title II Order’s argument that giving
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
Section 230 its plain meaning would be
‘‘an oblique’’ way to ‘‘settle the
regulatory status of broadband internet
access.’’ On the contrary, we agree that
‘‘it is hardly ‘oblique’ for Congress to
confirm in Section 230 that internet
access should be classified as an
unregulated information service when
elsewhere in the same legislation
Congress codifies a definition of
‘information services’ that was long
understood to include gateway services
such as internet access.’’ And while the
USTelecom court did not find this
definition determinative on the issue,
we find that ‘‘it is nonetheless a strong
indicator that Congress was more
comfortable with the prevailing view
that provision of internet access is not
a telecommunications service, and
should not be subject to the array of
Title II statutory provisions.’’ We find
inapplicable the USTelecom court’s
invocation of the principle that
‘‘Congress . . . does not alter the
fundamental details of a regulatory
scheme in vague terms or ancillary
provisions.’’ Section 230 did not alter
any fundamental details of Congress’s
regulatory scheme but was part and
parcel of that scheme, and confirmed
what follows from a plain reading of
Title I—namely, that broadband internet
access service meets the definition of an
information service. The legislative
history of Section 230 also lends
support to the view that Congress did
not intend the Commission to subject
broadband internet access service to
Title II regulation. The congressional
record reflects that the drafters of
Section 230 did ‘‘not wish to have a
Federal Computer Commission with an
army of bureaucrats regulating the
internet.’’ We likewise reject arguments
premised on the theory that we are
treating definitions in Section 230 and
231 as dispositive, rather than relying
on them to inform our understanding of
Congress’ intent as revealed by the text
and structure of the Act more broadly.
43. Section 231, inserted into the
Communications Act a year after the
1996 Act’s passage, similarly lends
support to our conclusion that
broadband internet access service is an
information service. It expressly states
that ‘‘internet access service’’ ‘‘does not
include telecommunications services,’’
but rather ‘‘means a service that enables
users to access content, information,
electronic mail, or other services offered
over the internet, and may also include
access to proprietary content,
information, and other services as part
of a package of services offered to
consumers.’’ Further, the carve-outs in
Section 231(b)(1)–(2) differentiate the
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
provision of telecommunications
services and the provision of internet
access service. It is hard to imagine
clearer statutory language. The
Commission has consistently held that
categories of telecommunications
service and information service are
mutually exclusive; thus, because it is
an information service, internet access
cannot be a telecommunications service.
Our interpretation of
‘‘telecommunications service’’ and
‘‘information service’’ as mutually
exclusive ways to classify a given
service thus demonstrates the relevance
of Section 231 notwithstanding that it
does not expressly define broadband
internet access service as an information
service. On its face then, this language
strongly supports our conclusion that,
under the best reading of the statute,
broadband internet access service is an
information service, not a
telecommunications service. Nothing in
the text of Section 231 reveals that the
use of ‘‘internet access service’’ there is
limited to dial-up internet access. To the
contrary, it would seem anomalous for
Congress only to exempt entities
providing dial-up internet access and
not other forms of internet access from
the prohibitions of Section 231(a). We
thus are unpersuaded by arguments
advocating a narrower interpretation of
‘‘internet access service’’ in Section 231.
44. We also find that the purposes of
the 1996 Act are better served by
classifying broadband internet access
service as an information service.
Congress passed the
Telecommunications Act to ‘‘promote
competition and reduce regulation.’’
Further, as a bipartisan group of
Senators stated, ‘‘[n]othing in the 1996
Act or its legislative history suggests
that Congress intended to alter the
current classification of internet and
other information services or to expand
traditional telephone regulation to new
and advanced services.’’ Or as Senator
John McCain put it, ‘‘[i]t certainly was
not Congress’s intent in enacting the
supposedly pro-competitive,
deregulatory 1996 Act to extend the
burdens of current Title II regulation to
internet services, which historically
have been excluded from regulation.’’ It
stands these goals on their head for the
Commission, as deployment of
advanced services reaches the
mainstream of Americans’ lives, to
perpetuate the very Title II regulatory
edifice that the 1996 Act sought to
dismantle. An information service
classification will ‘‘reduce regulation’’
and preserve a free market ‘‘unfettered
by Federal or State regulation.’’
45. Finally, we observe that the
structure of Title II appears to be a poor
PO 00000
Frm 00013
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
7863
fit for broadband internet access service.
Indeed, numerous Title II provisions
explicitly assume that all
telecommunications services are a
telephone service. For example, Section
221 addresses special provisions related
to telephone companies, Section 251
addresses the obligations of local
exchange carriers and incumbent local
exchange carriers, and Section 271
addresses limitations on Bell Operating
Companies’ provision of interLATA
services. For example, to obtain
authority to offer in-region interLATA
services, the BOCs have to offer a
number of functions of particular
relevance to the provision of telephone
service. Therefore, it is no surprise that
the Title II Order found that many
provisions of Title II were ill-suited to
broadband internet access services, and
the Commission was forced to, on its
own motion, forbear either in whole or
in part on a permanent or temporary
basis from 30 separate sections of Title
II as well as from other provisions of the
Act and Commission rules. We find that
the significant forbearance the
Commission deemed necessary in the
Title II Order strongly suggests that the
regulatory framework of Title II, which
was specifically designed to regulate
telephone services, is unsuited for the
dissimilar and dynamic broadband
internet access service marketplace.
B. Reinstating the Private Mobile Service
Classification of Mobile Broadband
Internet Access Service
46. Having determined that
broadband internet access service,
regardless of whether offered using
fixed or mobile technologies, is an
information service under the Act, we
now address the appropriate
classification of mobile broadband
internet access service under Section
332 of the Act. We restore the prior
longstanding definitions and
interpretation of this section and
conclude that mobile broadband
internet access service should not be
classified as a commercial mobile
service or its functional equivalent.
47. Background. Section 332 of Title
III, enacted by Congress as part of the
Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act of
1993 (the Budget Act), provides a
specific framework that applies to
providers of ‘‘commercial mobile
service.’’ The section defines
‘‘commercial mobile service’’ as: ‘‘any
mobile service . . . that is provided for
profit and makes interconnected service
available (A) to the public or (B) to such
classes of eligible users as to be
effectively available to a substantial
portion of the public, as specified by
regulation by the Commission.’’
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
7864
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
‘‘Interconnected service,’’ in turn, is
defined as ‘‘service that is
interconnected with the public switched
network (as such terms are defined by
regulation by the Commission).’’ In
1994, the Commission adopted
regulations implementing this section,
codifying the definition of ‘‘commercial
mobile service’’ under the term
‘‘commercial mobile radio service’’
(CMRS). Looking at the statute’s text,
structure, legislative history, and
purpose, the Commission defined the
‘‘public switched network’’ as ‘‘[a]ny
common carrier switched network,
whether by wire or radio, including
local exchange carriers, interexchange
carriers, and mobile service providers,
that use[s] the North American
Numbering Plan in connection with the
provision of switched services.’’ It
defined ‘‘interconnected service’’ as ‘‘a
service that gives subscribers the
capability to communicate . . . [with]
all other users on the public switched
network.’’
48. Section 332 distinguishes
commercial mobile service from
‘‘private mobile service,’’ defined as
‘‘any mobile service . . . that is not a
commercial mobile service or the
functional equivalent of a commercial
mobile service, as specified by
regulation by the Commission.’’ In 1994,
the Commission established its
functional equivalence test, which starts
with a presumption that ‘‘a mobile
service that does not meet the definition
of CMRS is a private mobile radio
service.’’ Overcoming this presumption
requires an analysis of a variety of
factors to determine whether the mobile
service in question is the functional
equivalent of commercial mobile
service, including ‘‘consumer demand
for the service to determine whether the
service is closely substitutable for a
commercial mobile radio service;
whether changes in price for the service
under examination, or for the
comparable commercial mobile radio
service would prompt customers to
change from one service to the other;
and market research information
identifying the targeted market for the
service under review.’’ Emphasizing the
high bar it had set, the Commission
expected that ‘‘very few mobile services
that do not meet the definition of CMRS
will be a close substitute for a
commercial mobile radio service.’’ We
note that, in another Order adopted
today, we are recodifying these factors
under Section 20.3 of the Commission’s
rules, but not modifying their substance.
49. The Act treats providers of
commercial mobile service as common
carriers, and the legislative history of
the 1996 Act suggests that Congress
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
intended the definition of
‘‘telecommunications service’’ to
include commercial mobile service. In
contrast, the Act prohibits the
Commission from treating providers of
private mobile service as common
carriers.
50. In 2007, the Commission found
that wireless broadband internet access
service was not a commercial mobile
service because it did not meet the
definition of an ‘‘interconnected
service’’ under the Act and the
Commission’s rules. It found that
wireless broadband internet access was
not ‘‘interconnected’’ with the ‘‘public
switched network’’ because it did not
use the North American Numbering
Plan, which limited ‘‘subscribers’ ability
to communicate to or receive
communication from all users in the
public switched network.’’ The
Commission concluded that Section 332
and the Commission’s rules ‘‘did not
contemplate wireless broadband
internet access service as provided
today’’ and that a commercial mobile
service ‘‘must still be interconnected
with the local exchange or
interexchange switched network as it
evolves.’’
51. In the Title II Order, the
Commission reversed course. First, the
Commission changed definitions of two
key terms within the definition of
commercial mobile service. It broadened
the definition of the term ‘‘public
switched network’’ to include services
that use ‘‘public IP addresses.’’ And it
redefined the term ‘‘interconnected
service’’ by deleting the word ‘‘all’’ from
the requirement that the service give
subscribers the capability to
communicate with ‘‘all other users on
the public switched network,’’ so that a
service would be interconnected even if
users of such a service could not
communicate with all other users. By
manipulating these definitions, the
Commission engineered a conclusion
that mobile broadband internet access
was interconnected with the public
switched network and was an
interconnected service under Section
332.
52. Second, the Title II Order found
that even if it had not changed the
definitions, it could change the scope of
the service to meet them. Specifically,
the Commission found that ‘‘users have
the ‘capability’ . . . to communicate
with NANP numbers using their
broadband connection through the use
of VoIP applications.’’ Accordingly it
found that, by including services not
offered by the mobile broadband
internet access service provider as part
of the service, mobile broadband
internet access service would now meet
PO 00000
Frm 00014
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
the regulatory definition of
‘‘interconnected service’’ adopted in
1994.
53. Third, the Title II Order eschewed
the functional equivalence test
contained in the Commission’s rules to
find that mobile broadband internet
access service was functionally
equivalent to commercial mobile
service. Rather than apply that test, the
Commission reasoned that the two were
functionally equivalent because ‘‘like
commercial mobile service, [mobile
broadband internet access service] is a
widely available, for profit mobile
service that offers mobile subscribers
the capability to send and receive
communications on their mobile device
to and from the public.’’
54. In the Internet Freedom Notice of
Proposed Rulemaking (NPRM) (82 FR
25568), the Commission proposed to
‘‘restore the meaning of ‘public
switched network’ under Section
332(d)(2) to its pre-Title II Order focus
on the traditional public switched
telephone network’’ and ‘‘to return to
our prior definition of ‘interconnected
service.’ ’’ The Commission further
proposed to return to the analysis of the
Wireless Broadband Internet Access
Order and find that mobile broadband
internet access service was a private
mobile service. Finally, it proposed to
reconsider the Title II Order’s departure
from the functional equivalence test
codified in our rules.
55. Discussion. We find that the
definitions of the terms ‘‘public
switched network’’ and ‘‘interconnected
service’’ that the Commission adopted
in the 1994 Second CMRS Report and
Order reflect the best reading of the Act,
and accordingly, we readopt the earlier
definitions. We further find that, under
these definitions, mobile broadband
internet access service is not a
commercial mobile service.
56. We find that the Commission’s
original interpretation of ‘‘public
switched network’’ was more consistent
with the ordinary meaning and
commonly understood definition of the
term and with Commission precedent.
On multiple prior occasions before
Section 332(d)(2) was enacted, the
Commission used the term ‘‘public
switched network’’ to refer to the
traditional public switched telephone
network. In 1981, for example, the
Commission noted that ‘‘the public
switched network interconnects all
telephones in the country.’’ In 1992, the
Commission described its cellular
service policy as ‘‘encourag[ing] the
creation of a nationwide, seamless
system, interconnected with the public
switched network so that cellular and
landline telephone customers can
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
communicate with each other on a
universal basis.’’ Courts also used the
term ‘‘public switched network’’ when
referring to the traditional telephone
network. Based on this history of usage
of the term, the Commission, in 1994,
tied its definition of the term ‘‘public
switched network’’ to the traditional
switched telephone network. We find
this approach appropriately reflects the
fundamental canon of statutory
construction that ‘‘unless otherwise
defined, words will be interpreted as
taking their ordinary, contemporary,
common meaning.’’ We find that the
legislative history of the Budget Act
further supports this view. One
commenter notes that the Budget Act
conferees chose the Senate version of
the relevant statutory definitions,
including the use of the term ‘‘public
switched network,’’ over the House
version, which used the term ‘‘public
switched telephone network,’’ and
argues that Congress thereby rejected
the latter term. We note, however, that
the conferees also expressly identified
the substantive differences between the
House and Senate versions of the
definitions, and notably absent from
their list was any contrast between the
Senate’s use of ‘‘public switched
network’’ and the House’s use of
‘‘public switched telephone network,’’
suggesting that the conferees did not
view the two terms as a significant
difference.
57. We also find that the
Commission’s prior interpretation is
more consistent with the text of Section
332(d)(2), in which Congress provided
that commercial mobile service must
provide a service that is interconnected
with ‘‘the public switched network.’’
We find that the use of the definite
article ‘‘the’’ and singular term
‘‘network’’ shows that Congress
intended ‘‘public switched network’’ to
mean a single, integrated network. We
therefore agree with commenters who
argue that it was not meant to
encompass multiple networks whose
users cannot necessarily communicate
or receive communications across
networks. Consistent with Congress’s
directive to define ‘‘the public switched
network,’’ the restored definition
reflects that the public switched
network is a singular network that
‘‘must still be interconnected with the
local exchange or interexchange
switched network as it evolves,’’ as
opposed to multiple networks that need
not be connected to the public
telephone network. That the
Commission’s original interpretation
better reflects Congressional intent is
further evidenced by the fact that,
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
although Congress has amended the
Communications Act and Section 332
on multiple occasions since the
Commission defined the term, it has
never changed the Commission’s
interpretation. As we further discuss
elsewhere in connection with the term
‘‘interconnected service,’’ we find the
best interpretation is to classify a service
under Section 332 based solely on the
nature of the service offered. Even if we
were to consider such applications,
however, we find that the public
switched telephone network and the
internet are and will continue to be
distinct and separate networks, and
cannot be considered a singular,
integrated network as intended by the
term ‘‘the public switched network.’’
The deployment of the Internet of
Things (IoT), for example, will mean a
dramatic increase in the number of nonVoIP-capable end-points, such as IPenabled televisions, washing machines,
and thermostats, and other smart
devices.
58. We also restore the definition of
‘‘interconnected service’’ that existed
prior to the Title II Order. Prior to that
Order, the term was defined under the
Commission’s rules as a service ‘‘that
gives subscribers the capability to
communicate to or receive
communication from all other users on
the public switched network.’’ The Title
II Order modified this definition by
deleting the word ‘‘all,’’ finding that
mobile broadband internet access
service should still be considered an
interconnected service even if it only
enabled users to communicate with
‘‘some’’ other users of the public
switched network rather than all. We
agree with commenters who argue that
the best reading of ‘‘interconnected
service’’ is one that enables
communication between its users and
all other users of the public switched
network. This reading ensures that the
public switched network remains the
single, integrated network that we find
Congress intended in Section 332(d)(2),
as reflected in the statutory definition of
‘‘interconnected service’’ as one that is
interconnected with ‘‘the public
switched network.’’ The Title II Order
rejected this reading on the ground that
the Commission has previously
recognized that interconnected services
may be limited in certain ways. While
an interconnected service is required to
provide its users with the capability to
communicate with or receive
communication from all other users of
the public switched network, the
Commission has permitted an
interconnected service to restrict access
to the public switched network in
PO 00000
Frm 00015
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
7865
certain limited ways (such as the
blocking of 900 numbers). This limited
exception to general access has existed
since the original definition of the term
‘‘interconnected service’’ was adopted,
and the record does not demonstrate
that it has caused confusion or
misunderstandings about what services
may be considered interconnected.
Accordingly, we will continue to apply
the definition of ‘‘interconnected
service’’ in this fashion, and we see no
need to codify any language further
clarifying the exception. We agree with
Verizon, however, that ‘‘[t]here is a
massive difference between limited,
targeted restrictions that deny access to
certain points on the network and the
situation envisioned by the Title II
Order, where millions of users on what
is ostensibly the same network are
incapable of reaching each other.’’
59. Some commenters who argue that
the Title II Order’s revised definitions
should be maintained point to
Congress’s delegation of interpretational
authority to the Commission and the
Commission’s previous position that it
could define the public switched
network based on new technology and
consumer demand. In defining the terms
‘‘public switched network’’ and
‘‘interconnected service’’ in the Second
CMRS Report and Order, however, the
Commission recognized that
commercial mobile service must still be
interconnected with the local exchange
or interexchange switched network, and
it stated that ‘‘any switched common
carrier service that is interconnected
with the traditional local exchange or
interexchange switched network will be
defined as part of that network for
purposes of our definition of
‘commercial mobile radio services.’ ’’
We disagree with commenters arguing
that, by not including IP addresses in
the definition of the public switched
network, the Commission would be
failing to recognize the evolution of
mobile network technologies that have
blurred the lines between circuit
switched and packet switched networks.
The Commission’s original decision
properly reflects that the public
switched network should not be defined
in a static way and should reflect that
the public switched network is
continuously growing and changing, but
also ensures that, as it grows and
evolves, the public switched network
remains a single integrated network
incorporating the traditional local and
interexchange telephone networks and
enabling users to send or receive
messages to or from all other users.
Further, although the Title II Order
found that the revised definitions
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
7866
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
adopted at that time were warranted as
better reflecting current technological
developments, including the ‘‘rapidly
growing and virtually universal use of
mobile broadband service’’ and the
‘‘universal access provided . . . by and
to mobile broadband,’’ the Commission
expressly noted that its determination
was ‘‘a policy judgment that section
332(d) expressly delegated to the
Commission, consistent with its broad
spectrum management authority under
Title III.’’ We find that this analysis
places undue weight on the wide
availability of a mobile service, as being
effectively available to a substantial
portion of the public is merely one of
the definitional criteria. The
Commission found that the updated
definitions would be consistent with
Congress’s intent to create a
symmetrical regulatory framework
among mobile services that were
similarly ‘‘broadly available’’ to the
public. While we agree that Congress
intended, in adopting Section 332, to
regulate similar mobile services
symmetrically, we do not believe that
Congress intended for the Commission
to regulate mobile services
symmetrically simply because they are
similarly ‘‘broadly available.’’ First,
being ‘‘effectively available to a
substantial portion of the public’’ is a
necessary, but not sufficient,
requirement for classification as
commercial mobile service. Second, as
noted, Congress set as the touchstone for
regulatory symmetry only those mobile
services that are ‘‘functionally
equivalent.’’ In light of definitional
analysis discussed above, as well as the
public policy considerations that we
have found to support our decision to
classify broadband internet access
service as an information service, we
find under the same authority that such
developments do not persuade us to
retain the modified definitions.
60. We find that mobile broadband
internet access service does not meet the
regulatory definition of ‘‘interconnected
service’’ that the Commission originally
adopted in 1994 and which we readopt
today, and therefore it does not meet the
definition of commercial mobile service.
As the Commission found in the
Wireless Broadband Internet Access
Order, ‘‘[m]obile wireless broadband
Internet access service in and of itself
does not provide the capability to
communicate with all users of the
public switched network’’ because it
does ‘‘not use the North American
Numbering Plan to access the Internet,
which limits subscribers’ ability to
communicate to or receive
communications from all users in the
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
public switched network.’’ Accordingly,
it is ‘‘not an ‘interconnected service’ as
the Commission has defined the term in
the context of section 332.’’
61. We disagree with the conclusion
in the Title II Order that, because an end
user can use a separate application or
service that rides on top of the
broadband internet access service for
interconnected communications, mobile
broadband internet access service meets
the definition of ‘‘interconnected
service.’’ We find that the definition of
‘‘interconnected service’’ focuses on the
characteristics of the offered mobile
service itself. Thus, the service in
question must itself provide
interconnection to the public switched
network using the NANP to be
considered an interconnected service.
Our interpretation is consistent with
Commission precedent that, prior to the
Title II Order, had classified a service
based on the nature of the service itself.
This interpretation is also consistent
with Section 332(d)(1), which defines
commercial mobile service as a service
that itself ‘‘makes interconnected
service available . . . to the public,’’
and with Section 332(d)(2), which
defines ‘‘interconnected service’’ as
‘‘service that is interconnected with the
public switched network.’’ These
statutory definitions focus on the
functions of the service itself rather than
‘‘whether the service allows consumers
to acquire other services that bridge the
gap to the telephone network.’’ Thus,
we are not persuaded by arguments that
‘‘applications such as Google Voice
reflect the fully interconnected nature of
the mobile broadband and legacy
telephone networks.’’ Our
determination reflects that the relevant
service must itself be an
‘‘interconnected service,’’ and not
merely a capability to acquire
interconnection. We further note that
viewing broadband internet access
service as a distinct service from
application layer services that may be
accessed by it, even if the applications
are pre-installed in the mobile device
offered by the provider, ensures that
similar mobile broadband internet
access services are not regulated in a
disparate fashion based on what
applications a particular provider
chooses to install in their offered
devices. This is consistent with the
fundamental purpose under Section 332
of regulatory symmetry between similar
mobile services, and also avoids
regulatory inconsistencies that would
result when mobile devices are brought
to a particular service provider by the
consumer that do not include the
provider’s choice of pre-installed apps.
PO 00000
Frm 00016
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
While OTI New America argues that the
need to obtain such apps to make an
interconnected call does not make
mobile broadband internet access
service different from traditional
telephone service, which has always
required customer premises equipment
to complete an interconnected call, we
find the analogy inapt. With traditional
CMRS, even where consumers obtain
their premises equipment or mobile
devices separately, the function of
interconnection is provided by the
purchased mobile service itself. Because
the focus is solely on the relevant
service provided, we also disagree that
physical connections between networks,
in and of themselves, establish that the
relevant services are interconnected,
and we further disagree that mobile
broadband internet access service
should be considered an interconnected
service simply because a separate
interconnected voice service may be
provided using the same packetswitched network layer.
62. Consistent with the Commission’s
analysis in the Wireless Broadband
Internet Access Order, the fact that
‘‘consumers are now able to use a
variety of Internet-enabled applications
that allow them to send calls and texts
to NANP end-points’’ does not make
mobile broadband internet access
service itself an interconnected service
as defined by our rules. The increased
use and availability of mobile VoIP
applications does not change the fact
that mobile broadband internet access as
a core service is distinct from the
service capabilities offered by
applications (whether installed by a
user or hardware manufacturer) that
may ride on top of it. When viewed as
a distinct service, it is apparent that
today’s mobile broadband internet
access service itself does not enable
users to reach NANP telephone numbers
and therefore cannot be considered an
interconnected service. We do not here
address whether IP-based services or
applications such as Wi-Fi Calling or
VoLTE would meet the definition of
‘‘interconnected service’’ under Section
332 and the Commission’s rules. We
disagree with OTI New America’s
argument that the growing availability
of Wi-Fi Calling provided by mobile
carriers that also offer mobile broadband
internet access service supports the
classification of mobile broadband
internet access service as a commercial
mobile service. The two are distinct
services and subject to separate
classification determinations. Similarly,
even if providers are increasingly
offering voice service and mobile
broadband internet access service
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
together, this does not support
classifying and regulating the latter in
the same way as the former. Providers
have long offered multiple services of
mixed classification, subject to the rule
that they are regulated as common
carriers to the extent they offer services
that are subject to Title II regulation.
63. Moreover, in light of the
determination above that mobile
broadband internet access service
should be restored to its classification as
an information service, and consistent
with our findings today that reinstating
this classification will serve the public
interest, we also find that it will serve
the public interest for the Commission
to exercise its statutory authority to
return to its original conclusion that
mobile broadband internet access is not
a commercial mobile service. We note
that commenters who support the Title
II Order’s revised definition of ‘‘public
switched network’’ do not dispute that
Congress expressly delegated authority
to the Commission to define the key
terms, i.e., ‘‘public switched network’’
and ‘‘interconnected service.’’ No one
disputes that, consistent with the
Commission’s previous findings, if
mobile broadband internet access
service were a commercial mobile
service for purposes of Section 332 and
were also classified as an information
service, such a regulatory framework
could lead to contradictory and absurd
results. Among these problems, as the
Commission explained in 2007, is that
a contrary reading of the Act would
result in an internal contradiction
within the statutory framework, because
Section 332 would require that the
service provider be treated as a common
carrier insofar as it provides mobile
wireless broadband internet access
service, while Section 3 clearly would
prohibit the application of common
carrier regulation of such a service
provider’s provision of that service.
Indeed, the Title II Order, like the 2007
Wireless Broadband Internet Access
Order, recognized and sought to avoid
the significant problems in construing
Section 332 in a manner that set up this
‘‘statutory contradiction’’ with the scope
of Title II. Construing the CMRS
definition to exclude mobile broadband
internet access service as an information
service similarly avoids this
contradiction, furthers the Act’s overall
intent to allow information services to
develop free from common carrier
regulations, and is consistent with the
public policy analysis in connection
with our determination to reclassify
mobile broadband internet access as an
information service. Further, it avoids
the absurd result of singling out mobile
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
providers of broadband internet access
service for such common carrier
regulation while freeing fixed
broadband internet access services from
such regulation, notwithstanding that,
as discussed elsewhere in this Order,
there is generally greater competition in
the provision of mobile broadband
internet access service than in fixed
broadband internet access service. We
note that wireless services similar to
mobile broadband internet access
service were not available in the market
place in 1993 when Congress adopted
Section 332 or, in 1996, when Congress
adopted the Section 3 definition of
‘‘telecommunication carrier.’’
64. In addition to finding that mobile
broadband internet access is not a
commercial mobile service, we also
adopt our proposal to reconsider the
Commission’s analysis regarding
functional equivalence in the Title II
Order. For the same reasons discussed
below with respect to our authority to
revisit the classification of broadband
internet access service, we disagree with
arguments regarding limits on the
Commission’s ability to revisit the Title
II Order’s findings regarding functional
equivalence. In addition, we note that
the Title II Order, in reaching the
conclusion that mobile broadband
internet access was a commercial
mobile service, relied in part on the
need to avoid a statutory contradiction
with its determination that the service
was a telecommunications service.
Given our decision to restore the
original classification of mobile
broadband internet access service as an
information service, this change
additionally warrants revisiting our
conclusions with regard to the
classification of mobile broadband
internet access service under Section
332. We find that the test for functional
equivalence adopted in the Second
CMRS Report and Order reflects the best
interpretation of Section 332. Under this
test, a variety of factors will be
evaluated to make a determination
whether the mobile service in question
is the functional equivalent of a
commercial mobile radio service,
including: Consumer demand for the
service to determine whether the service
is closely substitutable for a commercial
mobile radio service; whether changes
in price for the service under
examination, or for the comparable
commercial mobile radio service would
prompt customers to change from one
service to the other; and market research
information identifying the targeted
market for the service under review. In
contrast, as noted above, the Title II
Order based its finding of functional
PO 00000
Frm 00017
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
7867
equivalence on the notion that ‘‘like
commercial mobile service, [mobile
broadband Internet access] is a widely
available, for profit mobile service that
offers mobile subscribers the capability
to send and receive communications on
their mobile device to and from the
public.’’ Commenters who support the
classification of mobile broadband
internet access service as a commercial
mobile service similarly contend that
mobile broadband internet access
service shares no similarities with other
private mobile services such as taxi
dispatch services and that, in contrast,
‘‘there is no networked service more
open, interconnected, and universally
offered than mobile broadband Internet
access service.’’ We note that the statute
directs us to determine whether mobile
broadband internet access is
functionally equivalent to a commercial
mobile service, not whether it is
functionally dissimilar from certain
systems classified as private mobile.
65. We believe the test of functional
equivalence adopted in the Second
CMRS Report and Order hews much
more faithfully to the intent of Congress
than the approach applied in the Title
II Order or the analyses in the record
focusing on the extent of service
availability. If Congress meant for
widespread public access to a widely
used service to be the determining factor
for what is ‘‘functionally equivalent’’ to
a commercial mobile service, it would
not have included being
‘‘interconnected with the public
switched network’’ in the statutory
definition of the service. Indeed, the
relevant House Report, in describing
‘‘private carriers’’ that under the current
law were offering service ‘‘[f]unctionally
. . . indistinguishable’’ from carriers
classified as common carriers,
highlighted that these private carriers
were offering services interconnected
with the public switched network.
Although the Commission has
discretion to determine whether
services are functionally equivalent, we
find that the Title II Order’s reliance on
the public’s ‘‘ubiquitous access’’ to
mobile broadband internet access
service alone was insufficient to
establish functional equivalency. In
contrast, the test established in the
Second CMRS Report and Order
provides a thorough consideration of
factors that are indicative of whether a
service is closely substitutable in the
eyes of consumers for a commercial
mobile service.
66. Applying the test adopted by the
Commission in the Second CMRS
Report and Order, we find that mobile
broadband internet access service today
is not the functional equivalent of
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
7868
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
commercial mobile service as defined
by the Commission. We note again that,
under this test, services not meeting the
definition of commercial mobile service
are presumed to be not functionally
equivalent, a presumption particularly
intuitive here in light of the functional
differences between traditional
commercial mobile services like mobile
voice and today’s mobile broadband
services. The evidence on demand
substitutability only reinforces this
presumption. First, mobile broadband
internet access service and traditional
mobile voice services have different
service characteristics and intended
uses. Consumers purchase mobile
broadband internet access service to
access the internet, on-line video,
games, search engines, websites, and
various other applications, while they
purchase mobile voice service solely to
make calls to other users using NANP
numbers. Pricing and marketing
information similarly support the
conclusion that today mobile broadband
internet access service and traditional
mobile voice services are not ‘‘closely
substitutable.’’ Such evidence suggests,
for example, that mobile service
providers target different types of
customer groups when advertising
voice, as opposed to mobile broadband
internet access service. Moreover, at this
time, voice-only mobile services tend to
be much less expensive than mobile
broadband internet access services, and
they appear to be targeted to consumers
who seek low-cost mobile service.
Currently, for example, unlimited voice
and text only plans may range from $15
to $25 per month. In contrast, unlimited
mobile broadband internet plans may
range from $60 to $90 per month for a
single line. Nothing in the record
suggests that changing the price for one
service by a small but significant
percentage would prompt a significant
percentage of customers to move to the
other service. Accordingly, under the
functional equivalence standard
adopted in the CMRS Second Report
and Order, we find that mobile
broadband internet access today is not
the functional equivalent of commercial
mobile service. The two services have
different service characteristics and
intended uses and are not closely
substitutable for each other, as
evidenced by the fact that changes in
price for one service generally will not
prompt significant percentages of
customers to change from one service to
the other. We make a conforming
revision to the definition of
‘‘commercial mobile radio service’’ in
Section 20.3 of the Commission’s rules
to reflect our determination that mobile
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
broadband internet access service is not
the functional equivalent of commercial
mobile service.
C. Public Policy Supports Classifying
Broadband Internet Access Service as
an Information Service
67. While our legal analysis
concluding that broadband internet
access service is best classified as an
information service under the Act is
sufficient grounds alone on which to
base our classification decision, the
public policy arguments advanced in
the record and economic analysis
reinforce that conclusion. We find that
reinstating the information service
classification for broadband internet
access service is more likely to
encourage broadband investment and
innovation, furthering our goal of
making broadband available to all
Americans and benefitting the entire
internet ecosystem. For almost 20 years,
there was a bipartisan consensus that
broadband should remain under Title I,
and ISPs cumulatively invested $1.5
trillion in broadband networks between
1996 and 2015. Commenters who claim
recent growth in online video streaming
services is evidence of the need for Title
II regulation ignore the fact that the
growth of online video streaming
services was largely made possible by
the network investments made under
Title I and as such demonstrates instead
the success of the longstanding lighttouch framework under Title I. During
that period of intense investment,
broadband deployment and adoption
increased dramatically, as the combined
number of fixed and mobile internet
connections increased from 50.2 million
to 355.2 million from 2005 to 2015, and
even as early as 2011, a substantial
majority of Americans had access to
broadband at home. As of 2016, roughly
91 percent of homes had access to
networks offering 25 Mbps, and there
were 395.9 million wireless
connections, twenty percent more than
the U.S. population. Mobile data speeds
have also dramatically increased, with
speeds increasing 40-fold from the 3G
speeds of 2007. Cable broadband speeds
increased 3,200 percent between 2005
and 2015, while prices per Mbps fell by
more than 87 percent between 1996 and
2012.
68. Based on the record in this
proceeding, we conclude that economic
theory, empirical studies, and
observational evidence support
reclassification of broadband internet
access service as an information service
rather than the application of publicutility style regulation on ISPs. We find
the Title II classification likely has
resulted, and will result, in considerable
PO 00000
Frm 00018
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
social cost, in terms of foregone
investment and innovation. At the same
time, classification of broadband
internet access service under Title II has
had no discernable incremental benefit
relative to Title I classification. The
regulations promulgated under the Title
II regime appear to have been a solution
in search of a problem. Close
examination of the examples of harm
cited by proponents of Title II to justify
heavy-handed regulation reveal that
they are sparse and often exaggerated.
Moreover, economic incentives,
including competitive pressures,
support internet openness. We find that
the gatekeeper theory, the bedrock of the
Title II Order’s overall argument
justifying its approach, is a poor fit for
the broadband internet access service
market. Further, even if there may be
potential harms, we find that preexisting legal remedies, particularly
antitrust and consumer protection laws,
sufficiently address such harms so that
they are outweighed by the wellrecognized disadvantages of public
utility regulation. As such, we find that
public policy considerations support
our legal finding that broadband
internet access service is an information
service under the Act.
1. Title II Regulation Imposes
Substantial Costs on the Internet
Ecosystem
69. The Commission has long
recognized that regulatory burdens and
uncertainty, such as those inherent in
Title II, can deter investment by
regulated entities and, until the Title II
Order, its regulatory framework for
cable, wireline, and wireless broadband
internet access services reflected that
reality. Congress has similarly
recognized the burdens associated with
regulation. For example, the 1996 Act
states its purpose is to ‘‘reduce
regulation,’’ and directs the Commission
to regularly review regulations and
repeal those it deems unnecessary or
harmful to investment, competition, and
the public interest. This concern is welldocumented in the economics literature
on regulatory theory, and the record also
supports the theory that the regulation
imposed by Title II will negatively
impact investment. The balance of the
evidence in the record suggests that
Title II classification has reduced ISP
investment in broadband networks, as
well as hampered innovation, because
of regulatory uncertainty. The record
also demonstrates that small ISPs, many
of which serve rural consumers, have
been particularly harmed by Title II.
And there is no convincing evidence of
increased investment in the edge that
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
would compensate for the reduction in
network investment.
70. Investment by ISPs. As the
Commission has noted in the past,
increased broadband deployment and
subscribership require investment, and
the regulatory climate affects
investment. The mechanisms by which
public utility regulation can depress
investment by the regulated entity are
well-known in the regulatory economics
literature. The owners of network
infrastructure make long-term,
irreversible investments. In theory,
public utility regulation is intended to
curb monopoly pricing just enough that
the firm earns a rate of return on its
investments equivalent to what it would
earn in a competitive market. In
practice, public utility regulation can
depress profits below the competitive
rate of return for a variety of reasons.
This reduction in the expected return
reduces the incentive to invest.
Importantly, the risk that regulation
might push returns below the
competitive level also creates a
disincentive for investment.
71. We first look to broadband
investment in the aggregate and find
that it has decreased since the adoption
of the Title II Order. ISP capital
investment increased each year from the
end of the recession in 2009 until 2014,
when it peaked. In 2015, capital
investment by broadband providers
appears to have declined for the first
time since the end of the recession in
2009. And investment levels fell again
in 2016—down more than 3 percent
from 2014 levels. Although declines in
broadband capital investments have
occurred in the past with changes in the
business cycle, the most recent decline
is particularly curious given that the
economy has not experienced a
recession in recent years but rather has
been growing. While observing trends in
the data by itself cannot establish the
cause of directional movements, the
stark trend reversal that has developed
in recent years suggests that changes to
the regulatory environment created by
the Title II Order have stifled
investment. In addition to data trends,
the record contains a variety of other
studies, using different methodologies
which seek to determine how
imposition of public-utility style
regulation might affect ISPs’
investments.
72. Comparisons of ISP investment
before and after the Title II Order
suggest that reclassification has
discouraged investment. Performing
such a comparison, economist Hal
Singer concluded that ISP investment
by major ISPs fell by 5.6 percent
between 2014 and 2016. Singer
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
attempted to account for a few
significant factors unrelated to Title II
that might affect investment, by
subtracting some investments that are
clearly not affected by the regulatory
change (such as the accounting
treatment of Sprint’s telephone
handsets, AT&T’s investments in
Mexico, and DirecTV investments
following its acquisition by AT&T in the
middle of this period). In contrast, Free
Press presents statistics that it claims
demonstrate that broadband deployment
and ISP investment ‘‘accelerated’’ to
‘‘historic levels’’ after the Commission
approved the Title II Order. But Free
Press fails to account for factors such as
foreign investment and the appropriate
treatment of handsets as capital
expenditures, as Singer did.
73. A comparative assessment that
adjusted the Free Press and Singer
numbers so that they covered the same
ISPs, spanned the same time period, and
subtracted investments unaffected by
the regulatory change, found that both
sets of numbers demonstrate that ISP
investment fell by about 3 percent in
2015 and by 2 percent in 2016. A Free
State Foundation calculation using
broadband capital expenditure data for
16 of the largest ISPs reached a result
similar to Singer’s, but this analysis
simply compared actual ISP investment
to a trend extrapolated from pre-2015
data. These types of comparisons can
only be regarded as suggestive, since
they fail to control for other factors that
may affect investment (such as
technological change, the overall state of
the economy, and the fact that large
capital investments often occur in
discrete chunks rather than being
spaced evenly over time), and
companies may take several years to
adjust their investment plans.
Nonetheless, these comparisons are
consistent with other evidence in the
record that indicates that Title II
adversely affected broadband
investment. A separate comparison of
the United States’ ISP investment with
ISP investment in Europe also suggests
that ISP investment might decline
further if the U.S., under the Title II
Order, moves toward a regulatory
system more like Europe’s. A
USTelecom research brief finds that
European investment per capita is about
50 percent lower than broadband
investment in the U.S. per capita. As
some commenters point out, this study
compares the U.S. with the much more
regulatory European system, which
includes mandatory unbundling at
regulated rates. Thus, it presents a
picture of how investment could change
if the U.S. moves toward the European
PO 00000
Frm 00019
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
7869
system under Title II, not an assessment
of the direct results of the Title II Order.
74. The record also contains analyses
attempting to assess the predicted
causal effects of Title II regulation on
ISP investment and/or output. Some of
these studies are ‘‘natural experiments’’
that seek to compare outcomes
occurring after policy changes to a
relevant counterfactual that shows what
outcomes would have occurred in the
absence of the policy change. No single
study is dispositive, but methodologies
designed to estimate impacts relative to
a counterfactual tend to provide more
convincing evidence of causal impacts
of Title II classification. Having
reviewed the record of these studies, the
balance of the evidence indicates that
Title II discourages investment by
ISPs—a finding consistent with
economic theory. The record does not
provide sufficient evidence to quantify
the size of the effect of Title II on
investment. An additional type of
evidence is the effect of the Title II
Order on stock prices. According to that
study, in the short term, the decision
appears to have had little direct effect
on stock prices, except for a few cable
ISPs. That may reflect the forwardlooking, predictive capabilities of
market players.
75. Prior FCC regulatory decisions
provide a natural experiment allowing
this question to be studied. Scholars
employing the natural experiment
approach found that prior to 2003,
subscribership to cable modem service
(not regulated under Title II) grew at a
far faster rate than subscribership to
DSL internet access service (the
underlying ‘last mile’ facilities and
transmission which were regulated
under Title II). After 2003, when the
Commission removed line-sharing rules
on DSL, DSL internet access service
subscribership experienced a
statistically significant upward shift
relative to cable modem service. A
second statistically significant upward
shift in DSL internet access service
subscribership relative to cable modem
service occurred after the Commission
classified DSL internet access service as
an information service in 2005. This
evidence suggests that Title II
discourages not just ISP investment, but
also deployment and subscribership,
which ultimately create benefits for
consumers. While some commenters
contend that deployment and
subscribership continued to increase
after the Title II Order, such that nothing
is amiss, this casual observation does
not compare observed levels of
subscribership and deployment to a
relevant counterfactual that controls for
other factors.
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
7870
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
76. An assessment of how ISP
investment reacted to news of
impending Title II regulation suggests
that the threat of Title II regulation
discouraged ISP investment. Such
statistical analysis allows one to
compare the actual level of investment
with a counterfactual estimate of what
investment would have been in the
absence of the change in risk. This study
found that Chairman Genachowski’s
2010 announcement of a framework for
reclassifying broadband under Title II—
a credible increase in the risk of
reclassification that surprised financial
markets—was associated with a $30
billion–$40 billion annual decline in
investment in the U.S. Bureau of
Economic Analysis’ ‘‘broadcasting and
telecommunications’’ category between
2011 and 2015. The study attributes the
decline to the threat of Title II
regulation, rather than net neutrality per
se, because no similar decline occurred
when the FCC adopted the four
principles to promote an open internet
in 2005. Because the study’s measure of
investment data covers the entire
broadcasting and telecommunications
industries, the change in investment
measured in this study might be larger
than the change in broadband
investment associated with the threat of
Title II regulation. Accordingly, the
findings may be a more reliable
indicator of the direction of the change
in investment than the absolute size of
the change. At the very least, the study
suggests that news of impending Title II
regulation is associated with a reduction
in ISP investment over a multi-year
period.
77. Some commenters have argued
that this study does not identify the
effect of Title II on ISP investment,
because the ‘‘last mile’’ facilities and
transmission underlying DSL internet
access service (essentially incumbent
LEC broadband supply) were under
Title II before 2005, during the study’s
pre-treatment period. However, to the
extent that a fraction of the industry was
subject to Title II (and at the time the
bulk of broadband subscribers used
cable modem services that were not
regulated under Title II), this would
imply Ford’s negative result for
investment was understated.
78. The study is also disputed by the
Internet Association, which submitted
an economic study arguing that the
threat and eventual imposition of Title
II status on broadband internet service
providers in 2010 and 2015 did not have
a measurable impact on
telecommunications investment in the
U.S. While we appreciate the alternative
method and data sources introduced by
that study, several elements lead us to
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
discount its findings. The estimation of
the impact of events in both 2010 and
2015 relies partially on forecast rather
than actual data, which likely lessens
the possibility of finding an effect of
Title II on investment. In addition,
when examining cable and
telecommunications infrastructure
investment in the U.S., the study relies
on a regression discontinuity over time
model, thereby eliminating the use of a
separate control group to identify the
effect of policy changes. We believe use
of such a model in these circumstances
is unlikely to yield reliable results. The
Internet Association study claims that
its test of the 2010 effect did not use
forecast data. However, comparing the
reported number of observations in
Tables B1 and B2 of the study clearly
indicates that the same datasets were
used to estimate 2010 and 2015 effects.
Furthermore, we note that the Phoenix
Center attempted to replicate the results
of Table B1 and obtained strikingly
different results when excluding the
forecast data. Unfortunately, the
Phoenix Center chose to only estimate
Hooton’s baseline model, which did not
control for obviously confounding
factors such as the business cycle, and
therefore we place limited weight on the
Phoenix Center’s revisions.
79. In light of the foregoing record
evidence, we conclude that
reclassification of broadband internet
access service from Title II to Title I is
likely to increase ISP investment and
output. The studies in the record that
control the most carefully for other
factors that may affect investment (the
Ford study and the Hazlett & Wright
study) support this conclusion. Ford
controls for macroeconomic factors that
influence the overall economy using a
two-way fixed-effects model. Hazlett &
Wright’s analysis of the effects of Title
II on DSL subscribership cites regression
analysis that controls for factors
influencing the overall economy by
including Canadian DSL subscribership
as an explanatory variable.
Consequently, we disagree with
commenters who assert that Title II has
increased or had no effect on ISP
investment, given the failure of other
studies to account for complexity of
corporate decision-making and the
macroeconomic effects that can play a
role in investment cycles. We also
disagree with commenters who assert
that it may be too soon to meaningfully
assess the economic effects that Title II
has had on broadband infrastructure
investment.
80. Regulatory Uncertainty. The
evidence that Title II has depressed
broadband investment is bolstered by
other record evidence showing that Title
PO 00000
Frm 00020
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
II stifled network innovation. Among
the unseen social costs of regulation are
those broadband innovations and
developments that never see the light of
day. ISP investment does not simply
take the form of greater deployment, but
can also be directed toward new and
more advanced services for consumers.
Research and development is an
inherently risky part of any business,
and the Commission’s actions should
not introduce greater uncertainty and
risk into the process without a clear
need to do so. Numerous commenters
have stated that the uncertainty
regarding what is allowed and what is
not allowed under the new Title II
broadband regime has caused them to
shelve projects that were in
development, pursue fewer innovative
business models and arrangements, or
delay rolling out new features or
services. Even large ISPs with
significant resources have not been
immune to the dampening effect that
uncertainty can have on a firm’s
incentive to innovate. Charter, for
instance, has asserted that it has ‘‘put on
hold a project to build out its out-ofhome Wi-Fi network, due in part to
concerns about whether future
interpretations of Title II would allow
Charter to continue to offer its Wi-Fi
network as a benefit to its existing
subscribers.’’ Cox has also stated that it
has approached the ‘‘development and
launch of new products and service
features with greater caution’’ due to the
uncertainty created by the Title II
classification. And while new service
offerings can take a while to develop
and launch, Comcast cites ‘‘Title II
overhang’’ as a burden that delayed the
launch of its IP-based transmission of its
cable service, due to a year-long
investigation.
81. Utility-style regulation is
particularly inapt for a dynamic
industry built on technological
development and disruption. It is well
known that extensive regulation distorts
production as well as consumption
choices. Regulated entities are
inherently restricted in the activities in
which they may engage, and the
products that they may offer. Asking
permission to engage in new activities
or offer new products or services
quickly becomes a major preoccupation
of the utility. This is apparent upon a
casual observation of heavily-regulated
utilities, such as the U.S. power, water,
and mass transit systems. These are
industries where competition has been
effectively deemed impossible, run by
quasi-public monopolies that lack
incentives to invest, innovate, or even
properly maintain their facilities.
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
Within the communications industry, it
is apparent that the most regulated
sectors, such as basic telephone service,
have experienced the least innovation,
whereas those sectors that have been
traditionally free to innovate, such as
internet service, have greatly evolved. In
the communications industry,
incumbents have often used
Commission regulation under the
direction of the ‘‘public interest’’ to
thwart innovation and competitive entry
into the sector and protect existing
market structures. Given the unknown
needs of the networks of the future, it
is our determination that the utilitystyle regulations potentially imposed by
Title II run contrary to the public
interest.
82. The record confirms that concern
about ‘‘regulatory creep’’—whereby a
regulator slowly increases its reach and
the scope of its regulations—has
exacerbated the regulatory uncertainty
created by the Title II Order. Even at the
time of adoption, the Commission itself
did not seem to know how the Title II
Order would be interpreted. As thenChairman Wheeler stated in February
2015, ‘‘we don’t really know. No
blocking, no throttling, no fast lanes.
Those can be bright-line rules because
we know about those issues. But we
don’t know where things go next.’’ With
future regulations open to such
uncertainties, Title II regulation adds a
risk premium on each investment
decision, which reduces the expected
profitability of potential investments
and deters investment. For example, the
Title II Order did not forbear from ex
post enforcement actions related to
subscriber charges, raising concerns that
ex post price regulation was very much
a possibility. Further, providers have
asserted that although the Commission
forbore from the full weight of Title II
in the Title II Order, they were less
willing to invest due to concerns that
the Commission could reverse course in
the future and impose a variety of costly
regulations on the broadband industry—
such as rate regulation and unbundling/
open access requirements—placing any
present investments in broadband
infrastructure at risk. These concerns
were compounded by the fact that while
the Title II Order itself announced
forbearance from ex ante price
regulation, at the same time it imposed
price regulation with its ban on paid
prioritization arrangements, which
mandated that ISPs charge edge
providers a zero price. These threats to
the ISP business model have been felt
throughout financial markets. As Craig
Moffett of MoffettNathanson explained,
¨
‘‘[i]t would be naıve to suggest that the
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
implication of Title II, particularly when
viewed in the context of the FCC’s
repeated findings that the broadband
market is non-competitive, doesn’t
introduce a real risk of price
regulation.’’ These risks are not merely
theoretical: As CenturyLink contends,
financial analysts lowered industry
stock ratings due in part to the major
risks Title II posed to the industry,
which resulted in lower stock prices
and lost market capitalization.
83. For these reasons, ‘‘any rational
ISP will think twice before investing in
innovative business plans that might
someday be found to violate the
Commission’s undisclosed policy
preferences and thus give rise to a ceaseand-desist order and perhaps massive
forfeiture penalties.’’ We conclude that
this ever-present threat of regulatory
creep is substantially likely to affect the
risk calculus taken by ISPs when
deciding how to invest their
shareholders’ capital, potentially
deterring them from investing in
broadband, and to encourage them to
direct capital toward less inherentlyrisky business operations. Many ISPs
are part of integrated multi-sector
holding companies, which allows them
to more easily shift capital away from
sectors where their investments would
face greater regulatory risk, and toward
more investment-friendly sectors. We
find unpersuasive the alleged
inconsistencies between ISPs claiming
that the Title II Order decreased their
willingness or ability to invest in
broadband infrastructure, and their
statements to investors that the Title II
Order has not had a negative impact on
their broadband deployments. First,
some of the comments claiming that
corporate officers’ statements to
investors prove that Title II has
increased investment use highly
selective quotations that ignore other
statements to investors that imply the
opposite. Second, as other commenters
point out, the latter often constitute
statements susceptible to multiple
interpretations, such as AT&T CEO
Randall Stephenson stating that his
company planned to ‘‘deploy more fiber
next year than [it] did this year.’’ Third,
these ambiguous statements do not take
into account the relevant counterfactual
scenario in which Title II regulation had
not been adopted. Fourth, we observe
that some of the comments attempting
to highlight a discrepancy between
statements to investors and statements
in this proceeding simply show
executives stating that their business
practices will not change because they
were not engaged in the conduct
prohibited by the Title II Order, not that
PO 00000
Frm 00021
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
7871
the firms’ investment priorities
remained the same after the Title II
Order. As such, we disagree with
commenters who assert that maintaining
the Title II Order regime is the best
means of addressing regulatory
uncertainty.
84. Small ISPs and Rural
Communities. The Commission’s
decision in 2015 to reclassify broadband
internet access service as a
telecommunications service has had
particularly deleterious effects on small
ISPs and the communities they serve,
which are often rural and/or lowerincome. The record reflects that small
ISPs and new entrants into the market
face disproportionate costs and burdens
as a result of regulation. Many small
ISPs lack the extensive resources
necessary to comply with burdensome
regulation, and the record evinces a
widespread consensus that
reclassification of broadband internet
access service as a telecommunications
service has harmed small ISPs by
forcing them to divert significant
resources to legal compliance and
deterring them from taking financial
risks.
85. Small ISPs state that these
increased compliance costs and
regulatory burdens have forced them to
divert money and attention away from
planned broadband service and network
upgrades and expansions, thus delaying,
deferring, or forgoing the benefits they
would have brought ‘‘to their bottom
lines, their customers, and their
communities.’’ A coalition of National
Multicultural Organizations highlights
that the uncertainty inherent under Title
II ‘‘already has produced results that
slow needed innovation and broadband
adoption, effects that are most acutely
felt in rural and socioeconomicallychallenged urban communities.’’ The
record is replete with instances in
which small ISPs reduced planned, or
limited new, investment in broadband
infrastructure as a result of the
regulatory uncertainty stemming from
the adoption of the Title II Order.
Because the logical expectation that
Title II regulation would have
particularly harmful effects on small
ISPs and the communities they serve in
is borne out by strong record evidence
from a wide range of small ISPs, we are
unpersuaded by speculative suggestions
that small ISPs’ investment decisions
can be fully or primarily explained
based on other considerations such that
the effect of Title II regulation can be
neglected. The Wireless Internet Service
Providers Association (WISPA)
surveyed its members and found that
over 80 percent had ‘‘incurred
additional expense in complying with
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
7872
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
the Title II rules, had delayed or
reduced network expansion, had
delayed or reduced services and had
allocated budget to comply with the
rules.’’ The threat of ex post rate
regulation has hung particularly heavily
on the heads of small ISPs, ‘‘who are
especially risk-averse, causing them to
run all current and planned offerings
against the ‘just’ and ‘reasonable’ and
unreasonably discriminatory standards
of sections 201 and 202 of the Act.’’ The
effects have been strongly felt by small
ISPs, given their more limited resources,
leading to depressed hiring in rural
areas most in need of additional
resources.
86. Compounding the difficulties
faced by small ISPs, the record also
reflects that the ‘‘ ‘black cloud’ of
common carriage regulations’’ resulted
in increased difficulties for small ISPs
in obtaining financing. A coalition of 70
small wireless ISPs cited the uncertainty
created by the Title II Order as a major
reason that their costs of capital have
risen, preventing them from further
expanding and improving their
networks. The new regulatory burdens,
risks, and uncertainties combined with
‘‘diminished access to capital create a
vicious cycle—the regulatory burdens
make it more difficult to attract capital,
and less capital makes it more difficult
to comply with regulatory burdens.’’ A
coalition of 19 municipal ISPs cited
high legal and consulting fees necessary
to navigate the Title II Order, as well as
regulatory compliance risk as a reason
for delaying or abandoning new features
and services. While, of course, not all
small ISPs have faced these challenges,
there is substantial record evidence that
regulatory uncertainty resulting from
the Commission’s reclassification of
broadband internet access service in
2015 risks stifling innovation, and that
it has already done so with respect to
small ISPs, which ultimately harms
consumers.
87. We anticipate that the beneficial
effects of our decision today to restore
the classification of broadband internet
access service to an information service
will be particularly felt in rural and/or
lower-income communities, giving
smaller ISPs a stronger business case to
expand into currently unserved areas.
Enabling ISPs to freely experiment with
services and business arrangements that
can best serve their customers, without
excessive regulatory and compliance
burdens, is an important factor in
connecting underserved and hard-toreach populations. We are committed to
bridging the digital divide, and
recognize that small ISPs
‘‘disproportionately provide service in
rural and underserved areas where they
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
are either the only available broadband
service option or provide the only viable
alternative to an incumbent broadband
provider.’’ We anticipate that returning
broadband internet access service to a
light-touch regulatory framework will
help further the Commission’s statutory
imperative to ‘‘encourage the
deployment on a reasonable and timely
basis of advanced telecommunications
capability to all Americans’’ by helping
to incentivize ISPs to expand coverage
to underserved areas. We therefore
reject arguments that our classification
decision harms low-income
communities.
88. Investment at the Edge. Finally, to
more fully discern the impact of Title II,
we must look at investment throughout
the broadband ecosystem, including
investment and innovation at the edge,
as well as with other ecosystem
participants (manufacturers, etc.). We
agree with commenters who assert that
looking only at ISP investment ignores
investment that is occurring at the edge.
While there is tremendous investment
occurring at the edge, the record does
not suggest a correlation between edge
provider investment and Title II
regulation, nor does it suggest a causal
relationship that edge providers have
increased their investments as a result
of the Title II Order. Free Press argues
that since adoption of the Title II Order,
innovation and investment at the edge
has increased. While high growth rates
are associated with the internet
industry, the evidence presented does
not show the imposition of Title II
regulation on internet access service
providers caused recent edge provider
investment. That requires an estimate as
to what would have happened in the
absence of Title II regulation (e.g.,
analysis following the methods
employed in the studies of Ford, and of
Hazlett & Wright).
89. In fact, one could argue that in the
absence of Title II regulation, edge
providers would have made even higher
levels of investment than they
undertook. In many cases, the strongest
growth for a firm or industry predates
the Title II Order. For example, Free
Press highlights that the data
processing, hosting, and related services
industry increased capital expenditures
by 26 percent in 2015, a significant
increase in investment. However, in
2013, well before the 2014 Open
Internet NPRM that led to the Title II
Order, that industry increased
investment by over 100 percent.
Similarly, Netflix’s greatest relative
increase in capital expenditures
occurred in 2013. Amazon increased its
spending on technology and content,
which consists primarily of research
PO 00000
Frm 00022
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
and development expenses, by 28
percent in 2016, while in 2013 the
increase was 41 percent. We do not
claim that these data points prove that
edge provider investment would have
been greater in the absence of the Title
II Order, but we find that Free Press
does not demonstrate that there is a
significant difference in the investment
behavior of edge providers due to the
Title II Order.
2. Utility-Style Regulation of Broadband
Is a Solution in Search of a Problem
90. The internet was open before Title
II, and many economic factors support
openness. The internet thrived for
decades under the light-touch regulatory
regime in place before the Title II Order,
as ISPs built networks and edge services
were born. We find that the sparse
evidence of harms discussed in the Title
II Order—evidence repeated by
commenters in this proceeding as the
basis for adopting a Title II
classification—demonstrates that the
incremental benefits of Title II over
light-touch regulation are
inconsequential, and pale in
comparison to the significant costs of
public-utility regulation. We therefore
reject the argument that sparse evidence
of harms is sufficient to justify the
imposition of Title II.
91. The internet as we know it
developed and flourished under lighttouch regulation. It is self-evident that
the hypothetical harms against which
the Title II Order purported to protect
did not thwart the development of the
internet ecosystem. Edge providers have
been able to disrupt a multitude of
markets—finance, transportation,
education, music, video distribution,
social media, health and fitness, and
many more—through innovation, all
without subjecting the networks that
carried them to onerous utility
regulation. It is telling that the Title II
Order and its proponents in this
proceeding can point only to a handful
of incidents that purportedly affected
internet openness, while ignoring the
two decades of flourishing innovation
that preceded the Title II Order.
92. The first instance of actual harm
cited by the Title II Order involved
Madison River Communications, a small
DSL provider accused in 2005 of
blocking ports used for VoIP
applications, thereby foreclosing
competition to its telephony business.
Madison River entered into a consent
decree with the Enforcement Bureau,
paying $15,000 to the U.S. Treasury and
agreeing that it ‘‘shall not block ports
used for VoIP applications or otherwise
prevent customers from using VoIP
applications.’’ Vonage, an over-the-top
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
VoIP provider, later confirmed in press
reports that it had initiated a complaint
against Madison River at the
Commission and that other small ISPs
had blocked its VoIP services.
93. Next, the Title II Order referenced
Comcast’s throttling of BitTorrent, a
peer-to-peer networking protocol.
Comcast, which was at the time the
nation’s second-largest ISP, admitted
that it interfered with about a tenth of
BitTorrent TCP connections, and
independent investigations suggested
that Comcast interfered with over half of
BitTorrent streams. After receiving a
formal complaint about the practice, the
Commission found ‘‘that Comcast’s
conduct poses a substantial threat to
both the open character and efficient
operation of the internet, and is not
reasonable,’’ and ordered Comcast to
cease the interference. However, the
D.C. Circuit vacated the Commission’s
order in Comcast.
94. Madison River and ComcastBitTorrent—the anecdotes most
frequently cited in favor of Title II
regulation—demonstrate that any
problematic conduct was quite rare. The
more recent incidents discussed in the
Title II Order also show that since 2008,
few tangible threats to the openness of
the internet have arisen. First, in 2012,
AT&T restricted customers on certain
data plans from accessing FaceTime on
its cellular network for three months.
AT&T contended it did so due to
network management concerns, while
application developers argued the
restriction limited consumer choice.
Regardless of the merits, AT&T
ultimately reversed its decision within
three months and the decision did not
affect consumers who had data caps.
95. The final example—though not an
example of harm to consumers—
discussed in the Title II Order was
Comcast’s Xfinity TV application for the
Xbox, which was criticized for
exempting subscribers from their
Comcast data caps. However, the service
was provided as a specialized service,
similar to certain VoIP and video
offerings that use IP but are not
delivered via the public internet.
Accordingly, the Xfinity Xbox
application was not subject to the 2010
or 2015 rules, as it was a so-called ‘‘nonBIAS data service.’’ However, the Title
II Order further clouded this carve-out
for innovative services by threatening to
enforce the rules adopted under the
Order against ISPs if it deemed after the
fact, that those services were
‘‘functional equivalents’’ of broadband
internet access services, as the Open
Internet Order had done in 2010.
96. Certain commenters have claimed
that there have been other harms to
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
internet openness, but most of their
anecdotes do not entail harms that the
Title II Order purported to combat.
Electronic Frontier Foundation and the
Internet Engineers point to a number of
alleged practices by ISPs, including
stripping encryption from certain
communications, inserting JavaScript
code into third-party web pages,
sending search data to third parties, and
adding cookies. However, none of the
bright-line rules promulgated in the
Title II Order would have halted these
practices, and whether they are covered
by the ‘‘general conduct rule’’ is at best
unclear. Similarly, the claim among
several commenters that certain mobile
providers blocked Google Wallet is
misleading. Mobile providers refused to
support Google Wallet because it
required integration with the secure
element of the handset’s SIM card,
which mobile providers believed
introduced security vulnerabilities.
OTI’s argument about AT&T blocking
Slingbox—which ‘‘redirected a TV
signal’’ to the iPhone app—from its 3G
network in 2009 fails to provide support
for Title II regulation for a similar
reason, because as AT&T explained at
the time, ‘‘we don’t restrict users from
going to a website that lets them view
videos. But what our terms and
conditions prohibit is the transferring,
or slinging, of a TV signal to their
personal computer or smartphone.’’ In
an attempt to manage its 3G network,
AT&T restricted slinging to Wi-Fi, while
reiterating that consumers could still
access video streaming websites. We
also recognize the existence of
consumer complaints, but for the
reasons discussed in Part IV.B below,
we do not find them indicative of actual
harm that the Commission’s net
neutrality rules are intended to protect
against.
97. Because of the paucity of concrete
evidence of harms to the openness of
the internet, the Title II Order and its
proponents have heavily relied on
purely speculative threats. We do not
believe hypothetical harms,
unsupported by empirical data,
economic theory, or even recent
anecdotes, provide a basis for publicutility regulation of ISPs. Indeed,
economic theory demonstrates that
many of the practices prohibited by the
Title II Order can sometimes harm
consumers and sometimes benefit
consumers; therefore, it is not accurate
to presume that all hypothetical effects
are harmful. Intrusive, investmentinhibiting Title II regulation requires a
showing of actual harms, and after
roughly fifteen years of searching,
proponents of Title II have found
PO 00000
Frm 00023
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
7873
‘‘astonishing[ly]’’ few. Further, the
transparency rule we adopt today will
require ISPs to clearly disclose such
practices and this, coupled with existing
consumer protection and antitrust laws,
will significantly reduce the likelihood
that ISPs will engage in actions that
would harm consumers or competition.
To the extent that our approach relying
on transparency requirements,
consumer protection laws, and antitrust
laws does not address all concerns, we
find that any remaining unaddressed
harms are small relative to the costs of
implementing more heavy-handed
regulation.
98. Incentives. We find, based on the
record before us, that ISPs have strong
incentives to preserve internet
openness, and these interests typically
outweigh any countervailing incentives
an ISP might have. Consequently, Title
II regulation is an unduly heavy-handed
approach to what, at worst, are
relatively minor problems. Although the
Title II Order argued that ISPs were
incentivized to harm edge innovation, it
also conceded that ISPs benefit from the
openness of the internet. The Title II
Order found that ‘‘when a broadband
provider acts as a gatekeeper, it actually
chokes consumer demand for the very
broadband product it can supply.’’ We
agree. The content and applications
produced by edge providers often
complement the broadband internet
access service sold by ISPs, and ISPs
themselves recognize that their
businesses depend on their customers’
demand for edge content. It is therefore
no surprise that many ISPs have
committed to refrain from blocking or
throttling lawful internet conduct
notwithstanding any Title II regulation.
Finally, to the extent these economic
forces fail in any particular situation,
existing consumer protection and
antitrust laws additionally protect
consumers. We therefore find that Title
II, and the attendant utility-style
regulation of ISPs, are an unnecessarily
heavy-handed approach to protecting
internet openness.
99. The Open Internet and Title II
Orders claimed to base their actions on
a theory that broadband adoption is
driven by a ‘‘virtuous cycle,’’ whereby
edge provider development ‘‘increase[s]
end-user demand for [Internet access
services], which [drive] network
improvements, which in turn lead to
further innovative network uses.’’ While
the primary reason for this seems to be
concern about the exercise of market
power, footnote 68 suggests a secondary
reason: ISPs ‘‘will typically not take into
account the effect that reduced edge
provider investment and innovation has
on the attractiveness of the internet to
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
7874
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
end users that rely on other broadband
providers—and will therefore ignore a
significant fraction of the cost of
foregone innovation.’’ However, neither
the Open Internet Order nor our record
provide a mechanism to explain how
this would occur, and why the impact
on the ISP would not be proportional to
its own business, and so be fully
accounted for in its decisions, and
provides no evidence that even if
possible, there was a measurable impact
from such an effect. The Title II Order
concluded that Commission action was
necessary to protect this virtuous cycle
because ‘‘gatekeeper’’ power on the part
of ISPs might otherwise thwart it, as
ISPs ‘‘are unlikely to fully account for
the detrimental impact on edge
providers’ ability and incentive to
innovate and invest.’’ However, the
economic analysis in the Open Internet
Order and Title II Order was at best only
loosely based on the existing economics
literature, in some cases contradicted
peer-reviewed economics literature, and
included virtually no empirical
evidence.
100. We find it essential to take a
holistic view of the market(s) supplied
by ISPs. ISPs, as well as edge providers,
are important drivers of the virtuous
cycle, and regulation must be evaluated
accounting for its impact on ISPs’
capacity to drive that cycle, as well as
that of edge providers. The underlying
economic model of the virtuous cycle is
that of a two-sided market. Notably, the
two-sided market we discuss here is the
economic concept; we are not
attempting to define a market for
antitrust purposes. In a two-sided
market, intermediaries—ISPs in our
case—act as platforms facilitating
interactions between two different
customer groups, or sides of the
market—edge providers and end users.
The Open Internet Order takes the
position that edge provider innovation
drives consumer adoption of internet
access and platform upgrades. The key
characteristic of a two-sided market,
however, is that participants on each
side of the market value a platform
service more as the number and/or
quality of participants on the platform’s
other side increases. (The benefits
subscribers on one side of the market
bring to the subscribers on the other,
and vice versa, are called positive
externalities.) Thus, rather than a single
side driving the market, both sides
generate network externalities, and the
platform provider profits by inducing
both sides of the market to use its
platform. In maximizing profit, a
platform provider sets prices and
invests in network extension and
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
innovation, subject to costs and
competitive conditions, to maximize the
gain both sides of the market obtain
from interacting across the platform.
The more competitive the market, the
larger the net gains to subscribers and
edge providers. Any analysis of such a
market must account for each side of the
market and the platform provider.
101. Innovation by ISPs may take the
form of reduced costs, network
extension, increased reliability,
responsiveness, throughput, ease of
installation, and portability. These types
of innovations are as likely to drive
additional broadband adoption as are
services of edge providers. In 2016,
nearly 80 percent of Americans used
fixed internet access at home. There is
no evidence that the remaining nearly
one-fifth of the population are all
waiting for the development of
applications that would make internet
access useful to them. Rather, the cost
of broadband internet access service is
a central reason for non-adoption. ISP
innovation that lowers the relative cost
of internet access service is as likely as
edge innovation, if not more so, to
positively impact consumer adoption
rates. Indeed, ISPs likely play a crucial
role by offering, for example, lowmargin or loss-leading offers designed to
induce skeptical internet users to
discover the benefits of access. In
response to a larger base of potential
customers, the returns to innovation by
edge providers would be expected to
rise, thereby spurring additional
innovative activity in that segment of
the market.
102. Accordingly, arguments that ISPs
have other incentives to take actions
that might harm the virtuous cycle, and
hence might require costly Title II
regulation, need to be explained and
evaluated empirically. In a two-sided
market, three potential reasons for Title
II regulation arise: The extent to which
ISPs have market power in selling
internet access to end users; the extent
to which ISPs have market power in
selling to edge providers access to the
ISP’s subscribers (end users), which
seems to primarily be to what the
Commission and others appear to be
referring when using the term
‘‘gatekeeper’’; and the extent to which
the positive externalities present in a
two-sided market might lead to market
failure even in the absence (or because
of that absence) of ISP market power. In
considering each of these, we find that,
where there are problems, they have
been overestimated, and can be
substantially eliminated or reduced by
the more light-handed approach this
order implements.
PO 00000
Frm 00024
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
103. Our approach recognizes our
limits as regulators, and is appropriately
focused on the long-lasting effects of
regulatory decisions. Thus, we seek to
balance the harms that arise in the
absence of regulation against the harms
of regulation, accounting for, in
particular, the effects of our actions on
investment decisions that could
increase competition three to five or
more years from now. This is different
from forbidding certain behavior or a
merger on antitrust grounds due to the
likelihood of imminent, non-transitory
price increases. As a result, our
discussion of competition need not have
any implications for conventional
antitrust analysis. We note that our
reclassification of broadband internet
access service as an information service
leaves the usual recourse of antitrust
and consumer protection action
available to all parties. That is, heavyhanded Title II regulation is
unnecessary to enforce antitrust and
consumer protection laws.
104. Fixed ISPs Often Face Material
Competitive Constraints. The premise of
Title II and other public utility
regulation is that ISPs can exercise
market power sufficient to substantially
distort economic efficiency and harm
end users. However, analysis of
broadband deployment data, coupled
with an understanding of ISPs’
underlying cost structure, indicates
fixed broadband internet access
providers frequently face competitive
pressures that mitigate their ability to
exert market power. Therefore, the
primary market failure rationale for
classifying broadband internet access
service under Title II is absent.
Furthermore, the presence of
competitive pressures in itself protects
the openness of the internet. The theory
that competition is the best way to
protect consumers is the ‘‘heart of our
national economic policy’’ and the
premise of the 1996 Act. We therefore
find that the competition that exists in
the broadband market, combined with
the protections of our consumer
protection and antitrust laws against
anticompetitive behaviors, will
constrain the actions of an ISP that
attempts to undermine the openness of
the internet in ways that harm
consumers, and to the extent they do
not, any resulting harms are outweighed
by the harms of Title II regulation. Our
discussion of competitive effects, unless
otherwise specified, does not rely on or
define any antitrust market.
105. ISP Competition in Supplying
Internet Access to Households. Starting
with fixed internet access, including
fixed satellite and terrestrial fixed
wireless service, competition, with
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
whatever limitations may be inherent in
these different technologies, appears to
be widespread, at lower speeds for most
households (we make no finding as to
whether lower speed fixed internet
access services are in the same market
7875
as higher speed fixed internet access
services):
PERCENT OF U.S. POPULATION IN DEVELOPED CENSUS BLOCKS IN WHICH RESIDENTIAL FIXED BROADBAND ISPS
REPORTED DEPLOYMENT
[as of December 31, 2016]
Number of providers
Speed of at least:
3+
(%)
3 Mbps down and 0.768 Mbps up ...................................................................
10 Mbps down and 1 Mbps up ........................................................................
25 Mbps down and 3 Mbps up ........................................................................
106. However, because there are
questions as to the extent fixed satellite
and fixed terrestrial wireless internet
access service are broadly effective
competitors for wireline internet access
service, we do not rely on this data,
except to note that these services, where
available, place some competitive
constraints on wireline providers. Fixed
wireless and satellite subscriptions
2
(%)
97.0
93.6
43.9
decisions suggest that consumers
generally prefer fixed wireline services
to these, even at lower speeds. For
example, at bandwidths of 3 Mbps
downstream and 0.768 Mbps upstream,
satellite providers report deployment in
99.1 percent of developed census
blocks, but only account for 1.7 percent
of subscriptions, while terrestrial fixed
wireless providers report deployment in
1
(%)
2.8
5.7
32.6
0
(%)
0.1
0.6
19.1
0.1
0.1
4.4
38.5 percent of developed census
blocks, but only account for 0.9 percent
of all subscriptions. Focusing on
competition among wireline service
providers, and excluding DSL with
speeds less than 3 Mbps down and
0.768 Mbps up, shows less, but still
widespread, competition:
PERCENT OF U.S. POPULATION IN DEVELOPED CENSUS BLOCKS IN WHICH RESIDENTIAL BROADBAND WIRELINE ISPS
REPORTED DEPLOYMENT
[as of December 31, 2016]
Number of providers
Speed of at least:
3+
(%)
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
3 Mbps down and 0.768 Mbps up ...................................................................
10 Mbps down and 1 Mbps up ........................................................................
25 Mbps down and 3 Mbps up ........................................................................
107. While not reported, the percent
of households in developed census
blocks closely tracks the entries for the
percent of population in developed
census tracts. For example,
approximately 79.7 percent of U.S.
households are in a census block where
at least two wireline suppliers offer
speeds of at least 3 Mbps down and
0.768 Mbps up. This table understates
competition in several respects. First,
even two competing wireline ISPs place
competitive constraints on each other.
ISPs’ substantial sunk costs imply that
competition between even two ISPs is
likely to be relatively strong. Thus, to
the extent market power exists, it is
unlikely to significantly distort what
would otherwise be efficient choices. A
wireline ISP, anywhere it is active,
necessarily has made substantial sunk
investments. Yet, the cost of adding
another customer, or of carrying more
traffic from the same customers, is
relatively low. Accordingly, a wireline
ISP has strong incentives, even when
facing a single competitor, to capture
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
2
(%)
12.1
9.0
5.9
customers or induce greater use of its
network, so long as its current prices
materially exceed the marginal cost of
such changes. In addition, empirical
research finds that the largest benefit
from competition generally comes from
the presence of a second provider, with
added benefits of additional providers
falling thereafter, especially in the
presence of large sunk costs. Indeed, a
wireline provider may be willing to cut
prices to as low as the incremental cost
of supplying a new customer. Thus, in
this industry, even two active suppliers
in a location can be consistent with a
noticeable degree of competition, and in
any case, can be expected to produce
more efficient outcomes than any
regulated alternative. We do not claim
that a second wireline provider results
in textbook perfect competition, but
rather, given ISP recovery of sunk
investments becomes more difficult as
competition increases, and the critical
nature of allowing such recovery,
market outcomes may well ensure
approximately competitive rates of
PO 00000
Frm 00025
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
1
(%)
67.2
58.5
45.2
0
(%)
16.2
26.3
39.6
4.4
6.2
9.2
return. Other industries with large sunk
costs have shown that ‘‘price declines
with the addition of the first competitor,
but drops by very little thereafter.’’
Nothing in this order should be
construed as finding that these
statements appropriately characterize
the addition of the first fixed wireline
competitor in a particular context, only
that in general such an addition likely
will have a material impact on moving
prices toward competitive levels.
108. Second, competitive pressures
often have spillover effects across a
given corporation, meaning an ISP
facing competition broadly, if not
universally, will tend to treat customers
that do not have a competitive choice as
if they do. This is because acting badly
in uncompetitive areas may be
operationally expensive (i.e., requiring
different equipment, different policies,
different worker training, and different
call centers to address differing
circumstances) and reputationally
expensive (e.g., even if behavior is
confined to an uncompetitive market,
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
7876
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
customers in competitive markets may
churn after learning about such
behavior). Accordingly (and
unsurprisingly), most ISPs actively try
to minimize the discrepancies in their
terms of service, network management
practices, billing systems, and other
policies—even if they offer different
service tiers or pricing in different areas.
Approximately 79 percent of U.S.
households are found in census blocks
that at least two wireline ISPs report
serving, and approximately another 8
percent of households are in census
blocks where the unique wireline ISP
providing service in the census block
faces competition from a rival in 90
percent of the blocks it serves. Such
ISPs included the top ten ISPs when
ranked by covered census blocks, and
also when ranked by households in
covered census blocks, except the ninth,
Windstream. Our conclusions do not
hinge on finding effective competition
everywhere. We find that competition
exists in various forms nearly
everywhere and to the extent that
effective competition is not universal,
the costs of Title II regulation outweigh
the benefits of our more light-touch
approach.
109. The Commission’s prior findings
on churn in the broadband marketplace
do not dissuade us from concluding that
wireline broadband ISPs often face
competitive pressures. Although the
Commission has previously found
voluntary churn rates for broadband
service to be quite low, a view which
some commenters echo, substantial,
quantified evidence in the record
dissuades us from repeating that finding
here. Regardless, even if high churn
rates make market power unlikely, low
churn rates do not per se indicate
market power. For example, they may
reflect competitive actions taken by ISPs
to attract customers to sign up for
contracts, and to retain existing
customers, such as discount and bonus
offers. Moreover, actions such as these,
and others, are indicative of
competition. For example, ISPs engage
in a significant degree of advertising,
aiming to draw new subscribers and
convince subscribers to other fixed ISPs
to switch providers. Similarly, ISPs
employ ‘‘save desks’’ often taking
aggressive actions to convince
subscribers seeking service cancellation
to continue to subscribe, often at a
discounted price. Thus, the record
indicates material competition for
customers regardless of churn levels.
110. There is even greater competition
in mobile wireless. Mobile wireless ISPs
face competition in most markets, with
widespread and ever extending head-tohead competition between four major
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
carriers. As of January 2017, at least four
wireless broadband service providers
covered approximately 92 percent of the
U.S. population with 3G technology or
better. Even in rural areas at least four
service providers covered
approximately 69 percent of the
population. These coverage estimates
represent deployment of mobile
networks and do not indicate the extent
to which providers offer service to
residents in the covered areas.
111. Both the Title II Order and its
supporters in the current proceeding fail
to properly account for the pressure
mobile internet access exerts on fixed,
including fixed wireline, internet access
supply. While we recognize that fixed
and mobile internet access have
different characteristics and capabilities,
for example, typically trading off speed
and data caps limits against mobility,
increasing numbers of internet access
subscribers are relying on mobile
services only. In 2015, one in five
households used only mobile internet
access service to go online at home (up
from one in ten in 2013), and close to
15 percent of households with incomes
in excess of $100,000 (up from six
percent in 2013), exclusively used
mobile internet access service at home.
New America/OTI notes that this study
states that low-income Americans are
far more likely to become mobile
dependent than consumers who have
higher levels of income. However, as
noted above, this same study by the U.S.
Census Bureau, which includes data
collected from nearly 53,000
households, also found a significant
increase in mobile-only use by higherincome households, and that the growth
in the proportion of high-income
households that exclusively use mobile
internet service at home is accelerating.
Several commenters discussed their
own views on the extent to which
mobile wireless might exert competitive
pressure in some instances. Competition
constrains a firm’s prices if the firm is
prevented from raising price to levels
that absent switching to competitors,
would increase the firm’s profits. The
extent of the switching need not be
large. For example, with constant unit
costs, a 5% price increase would be
prevented if that would lead to slightly
less than 5% of the firm’s customers to
either stop consuming altogether or to
switch to a rival. Suppliers of internet
access service are likely to be more
sensitive to customer loss than the case
with constant marginal cost, since in
general the marginal costs of internet
access service fall as subscriber numbers
increase, meaning, in addition to the
revenues lost due to leaving customers,
PO 00000
Frm 00026
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
profits are also eroded due to a rise in
the average cost of supplying those who
remain. With the advent of 5G
technologies promising sharply
increased mobile speeds in the near
future, the pressure mobile exerts in the
broadband market place will become
even more significant.
112. ISP Competition in Supplying
Edge Providers Access to End Users. On
the other side of the market, to the
extent ISPs have market power in
supplying edge providers, ISP prices to
edge providers could distort economic
efficiency (a potential harm that is
distinct from anticompetitive behavior
or because of a failure to internalize a
relevant externality). Loosely speaking,
such power over an edge provider can
arise under one of two conditions: The
ISP has conventional market power over
the edge provider because it controls a
substantial share of (perhaps a specific
subset of) end-user subscribers that are
of interest to the edge provider, or that
edge provider’s customers only
subscribe to one ISP (a practice known
as single homing).
113. Narrowly focusing on fixed ISPs,
Comcast, the largest wireline ISP, has
approximately one quarter of all
residential subscribers in the US, while
at speeds of at least 25 Mbps down and
3 Mbps up, the Herfindahl-Hirschman
Index measure of concentration for the
supply of access to residential fixed
broadband internet access service
subscribers meets the Department of
Justice (DOJ) designation of ‘‘moderately
concentrated’’ (DOJ considers a market
with an HHI value of between 1,500 and
2,500 to be moderately concentrated):
HHI OF SERVED RESIDENTIAL FIXED
INTERNET
ACCESS
BROADBAND
SERVICE SUBSCRIBERS
[as of December 31, 2016]
Speed
3 Mbps down and 0.768
Mbps up ............................
10 Mbps down and 1 Mbps
up ......................................
25 Mbps down and 3 Mbps
up ......................................
HHI
1,473
1,743
2,208
114. Large shares of end-user
subscribers, and/or market
concentration, however, do not seem a
likely source or indicator of
conventional market power capable of
significantly distorting efficient choices,
with the possible exception of edge
providers whose services require
characteristics currently only available
on high-speed fixed networks (such as
video, which requires both high speeds
and substantial monthly data
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
allowances, and gaming and certain
other applications, which require high
speeds and low latency). Given
Comcast’s market share, even a fledgling
edge provider that can only be viable in
the long term if it offers service to three
quarters of broadband subscribers, may
not depend on gaining access to any
single provider. And calculating market
shares for wireline ISPs based on their
end users may be too simplistic if edge
providers can reach end users at
locations other than their homes, such
as at work, or through a mobile ISP. We
reject claims that we should entirely
neglect this possibility based on
assertions that users might be limited in
their ability or willingness to switch
between different options for broadband
internet access in unspecified
circumstances and for unspecified
reasons. In addition, ISPs have good
incentives to encourage new entrants
that bring value to end users, both
because such new entrants directly
increase the value of the platform’s
service, and because they place
competitive pressure on other edge
providers, forcing lower prices, again
increasing the value of the platform’s
service. Moreover, those smaller edge
providers may benefit from tiered
pricing, such as paid prioritization, as a
means of gaining entry. If the entrant
offers a more valuable service than an
incumbent, then this would be a
profitable strategy, and while it is
common to claim new entrants would
not have the deep pockets necessary to
implement such an entry strategy, new
economy startups have demonstrated
that capital markets are willing to
provide funds for potentially profitable
ideas, despite high failure rates,
presumably because of the large
potential gains when an entrant is
successful. Examples of successful new
entrants that started behind dominant
incumbents, include Google (against
established search engines such as
Yahoo, and the map provider,
MapQuest), Amazon (against traditional
bricks and mortar storefronts), and
Facebook (against MySpace). In fact,
some edge providers might consider
reaching end users on mobile devices to
be roughly as valuable as, or more
valuable than, reaching end users on
wireline networks.
115. In addition, larger edge
providers, such as Amazon, Facebook,
Google and Microsoft, likely have
significant advantages that would
reduce the prospect of inefficient
outcomes due to ISP market power. For
example, the market capitalization of
the smallest of these five companies,
Amazon, is more than twice that of the
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
largest ISP, Comcast, and the market
capitalization of Google alone is greater
than every cable company in America
combined. Action by these larger edge
providers preventing or reducing the
use of ISP market power could spill over
to smaller edge providers, and in any
case, is unlikely to anticompetitively
harm them given existing antitrust
protections (since arrangements
between an ISP and a large established
edge provider must be consistent with
antitrust law). Consequently, any market
power even the largest ISPs have over
access to end users is limited in the
extent it can distort edge provider
decisions (or those of their end users).
116. Despite the preceding analysis, a
second claim is made that relies solely
on the second factor, single homing:
‘‘regardless of the competition in the
local market for broadband internet
access, once a consumer chooses a
broadband provider, that provider has a
monopoly on access to the subscriber
. . . Once the broadband provider is the
sole provider of access to an end user,
this can influence that network’s
interactions with edge providers, end
users, and others.’’ Commenters have
echoed this ‘‘terminating access
monopoly’’ concern. This argument is
often conflated with arguments about
retail competition more generally, but it
is a distinct concept that has been
endorsed by the FCC and the courts in
various contexts. The focus on edge
`
providers’ bargaining position vis-a-vis
ISPs is warranted in light of the fact that
any gatekeeper power applies to edge
providers, not end users. The Title II
Order contended that these forces
applied to all ISPs, whether large or
small, fixed or mobile, fiber or satellite,
and ‘‘therefore [it] need not consider
whether market concentration gives
broadband providers the ability to raise
prices.’’
117. As a blanket statement, this
position is not credible. It is unlikely
that any ISP, except the very largest,
could exercise substantial market power
in negotiations with Google or Netflix,
but almost certainly no small wireless
ISP, or a larger but still small rural cable
company or incumbent LEC, could do
so. Further, from the perspective of
many edge providers, end users do not
single home, but subscribe to more than
one platform (e.g., one fixed and one
mobile) capable of granting the end user
effective access to the edge provider’s
content (i.e., they multi-home). As the
Title II Order acknowledges, to the
extent multihoming occurs in the use of
an application, there is no terminating
monopoly.
118. Moreover, to the extent a
terminating monopoly exists for some
PO 00000
Frm 00027
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
7877
edge providers, and it is not offset or
more than offset by significant
advantages, there is the question of the
extent to which the resulting prices are
economically inefficient. A terminating
(access) monopoly arises when
customers on one side of the market,
roughly speaking end users in our case,
single home with little prospect of
switching to another platform in the
short run, while customers on the other
side, roughly speaking edge providers in
our case, find it worthwhile to multihome. The terminating monopoly differs
from conventional market power
because it can arise despite effective
competition between platforms. In that
case, platforms must vigorously
compete for single-homing end users,
but have less need to compete for edge
providers, who subscribe to all
platforms. Such an arrangement is
mutually reinforcing. Single homers can
reach all the multi-homers despite only
subscribing to one platform. Multihomers must subscribe to all platforms
to reach all single homers. This means
each ISP faces strong pressures to cut
prices to end users, but does not face
similar pressures in pricing to edge
providers. However, ISPs are unlikely to
earn supranormal profits, so any
markups earned from edge providers in
excess of total costs are generally passed
through to end users. While such an
outcome generally will not be efficient,
there is no general presumption about
the extent of that inefficiency, or even
if prices to the multi-homers ideally
should be lower than would emerge in
the absence of a termination monopoly.
In the present case, there is no
substantive evidence in the record that
demonstrates how different efficient
prices to edge providers would be from
the prices that would emerge without
rules banning paid prioritization or
prohibiting ISPs from charging
providers at all.
119. Lastly, we find the record
presents no compelling evidence that
any inefficiencies, to the extent they
exist, justify Title II regulation. There is
no empirical evidence that the likely
effects from conventional market power
or the terminating monopoly, to the
extent they exist, are likely to be
significant, let alone outweigh the
harmful effects of Title II regulation. For
all these reasons, we find no case for
supporting Title II regulation of ISP
prices to edge providers. We note that
the terminating monopoly problem in
voice telecommunications is one created
by common-carriage regulation, not one
solved by it. Specifically, carriers must
interconnect with each other and
originating carriers must pay
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
7878
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
terminating carriers rates set by the
terminating carrier in their tariff (with
some government oversight). That leads
to a ‘‘bargaining’’ situation where one
party sets the terms of the deal and the
other must accept it or complain to the
regulator—in other words, the
regulations prohibit a normal free
market from developing. Such
regulatory requirements do not exist in
broadband. Furthermore, two additional
aspects unique to the traditional
telephone market created those
problems: (1) Voice call originators, who
are (with the exception of reverse charge
calls) the analogue to edge providers in
voice-telecommunications, do not
directly negotiate with the carrier that
sets call termination charges, but rather
only have a relationship with the call
originating carrier. However, the
originating carrier gains from high call
termination charges when it terminates
calls on its own network, so faces a
conflict of interest when negotiating call
termination charges on behalf of its
subscribers. In fact, such a regime
provides carriers with a mechanism for
using the input price of call termination
to collude on retail prices. In contrast,
edge providers can directly connect
with an ISP to reach that ISP’s end
users, without seeking the ISP’s help to
terminate on another ISP’s network
(unlike in voice telecommunications), or
can use intermediaries such as Cogent
and Akamai, who largely do not
terminate traffic to their own end users,
so do not face the conflict that voice
carriers face when negotiating
termination charges. (2) Even if call
originating carriers had good incentives
to negotiate reasonable termination
charges, regulation that requires
interconnection, but does not
appropriately regulate termination
charges, seriously weakens their ability
to obtain reasonable rates. Threatening
to not interconnect is not an available
negotiating ploy in telecommunications,
but is one available to edge providers,
especially larger ones, in negotiating
with ISPs. Moreover, historically voice
telephony consisted of geographic
monopolies, making it pointless for one
carrier to threaten another with
disconnection since the end users of the
disconnected carrier could not switch to
a different carrier. Again, this is not true
for internet access.
120. Externalities Associated With
General-Purpose Technologies Are Not
a Convincing Rationale for Title II
Regulation. Some commenters make
somewhat inchoate arguments that ISPs
should not be permitted to treat
different edge providers’ content
differently or charge more than a zero
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
price because the internet is a ‘‘general
purpose technology’’ and/or the services
of some edge providers create positive
externalities that the edge providers
cannot appropriate. Hogendorn may
propose the most coherent version of
this argument: Because the internet is a
general purpose technology (GPT),
when an ISP sets a price to any edge
provider, the ISP does not take into
account the positive externalities
generated by the broad (e.g., GPT) use of
those edge providers’ applications (just
as edge providers do not).
Unfortunately, these commentators fail
to define or substantiate the extent of
the problem, if any; fail to demonstrate
how much the situation would be
improved by requiring
nondiscriminatory treatment of all edge
providers; do not explain why, if
nondiscriminatory treatment is
required, it should be at a zero price; do
not assess whether the costs of such an
intervention would be offset by the
benefits; and do not consider whether
other less regulatory measures would be
more appropriate. For example, ISPs are
one of many input suppliers to edge
providers, so taxing only ISPs would
create distortions in edge provider
provision which could offset any
(undemonstrated) benefits such tax
would bring. These problems are more
acute if only specific (as yet
unidentified) edge providers generate
positive externalities in supply. Instead,
these commenters seek to apply Title II
regulation to all ISPs, and consider the
solution to their concern that certain
services or the internet itself might be
inefficiently undersupplied (for reasons
well beyond the control of ISPs) to be
a ban on ISPs only (and not other input
suppliers of edge providers) charging
edge providers any price. We reject this
approach as unreasonable and
unreasoned.
3. Pre-Existing Consumer Protection and
Competition Laws Protect the Openness
of the Internet
121. In the unlikely event that ISPs
engage in conduct that harms internet
openness, despite the paucity of
evidence of such incidents, we find that
utility-style regulation is unnecessary to
address such conduct. Other legal
regimes—particularly antitrust law and
the FTC’s authority under Section 5 of
the FTC Act to prohibit unfair and
deceptive practices—provide protection
for consumers. These long-established
and well-understood antitrust and
consumer protection laws are wellsuited to addressing any openness
concerns, because they apply to the
whole of the internet ecosystem,
including edge providers, thereby
PO 00000
Frm 00028
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
avoiding tilting the playing field against
ISPs and causing economic distortions
by regulating only one side of business
transactions on the internet.
122. Consumer Protection. The FTC
has broad authority to protect
consumers from ‘‘unfair or deceptive
acts or practices.’’ As the nation’s
premier consumer protection agency,
the FTC has exercised its authority,
which arises from Section 5 of the FTC
Act, to protect consumers in all sectors
of the economy. The FTC has used its
Section 5 authority to enjoin some of the
practices at issue in this proceeding,
such as throttling. The FTC is
prohibited under the FTC Act from
regulating common carriers. As a result,
the Commission’s classification of
broadband internet access service as a
common carriage telecommunications
service stripped the FTC of its authority
over ISPs. Therefore, as discussed in
greater detail below, the return to Title
I will increase the FTC’s effectiveness in
protecting consumers. Today’s
reclassification of broadband internet
access service restores the FTC’s
authority to enforce any commitments
made by ISPs regarding their network
management practices that are included
in their advertising or terms and
conditions, as the FTC did so
successfully in FTC v. TracFone. The
FTC’s unfair-and-deceptive-practices
authority ‘‘prohibits companies from
selling consumers one product or
service but providing them something
different,’’ which makes voluntary
commitments enforceable. The FTC also
requires the ‘‘disclos[ur]e [of] material
information if not disclosing it would
mislead the consumer,’’ so if an ISP
‘‘failed to disclose blocking, throttling,
or other practices that would matter to
a reasonable consumer, the FTC’s
deception authority would apply.’’
Today’s reclassification also restores the
FTC’s authority to take enforcement
action against unfair acts or practices.
An unfair act or practice is one that
creates substantial consumer harm, is
not outweighed by countervailing
benefits to consumers, and that
consumers could not reasonably have
avoided. A unilateral change in a
material term of a contract can be an
unfair practice. The FTC’s 2007 Report
on Broadband Industry Practices raises
the possibility that an ISP that starts
treating traffic from different edge
providers differently without notifying
consumers and obtaining their consent
may be engaging in a practice that
would be considered unfair under the
FTC Act.
123. Many of the largest ISPs have
committed in this proceeding not to
block or throttle legal content. These
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
commitments can be enforced by the
FTC under Section 5, protecting
consumers without imposing publicutility regulation on ISPs. As discussed
below, we believe that case-by-case, ex
post regulation better serves a dynamic
industry like the internet and reduces
the risk of over-regulation. We also
reject assertions that the FTC has
insufficient authority, because, as
Verizon argues, ‘‘[i]f broadband service
providers’ conduct falls outside [the
FTC’s] grant of jurisdiction—that is, if
their actions cannot be described as
anticompetitive, unfair, or deceptive—
then the conduct should not be banned
in the first place.’’ In addition to
rejecting claims that the FTC’s authority
is insufficient, we also reject arguments
that it lacks the necessary expertise to
protect consumers in this area. The
comments by the FTC’s Acting
Chairman in this proceeding persuade
us of that agency’s understanding of the
issues and of its ability to resume
oversight of ISP practices. Just as
importantly, any loss of expertise is
outweighed by the benefits of having a
single expert consumer protection
agency overseeing the entire internet
ecosystem. We anticipate sharing
information and expertise with the FTC
as we work together to protect
consumers under the framework
adopted today. And the transparency
rule that we adopt today should allay
any concerns about the ambiguity of ISP
commitments, by requiring ISPs to
disclose if the ISPs block or throttle
legal content. For the same reasons, the
transparency rule allows us to reject the
argument that antitrust and consumer
protection enforcers cannot detect
problematic conduct. Finally, we expect
that any attempt by ISPs to undermine
the openness of the internet would be
resisted by consumers and edge
providers. We also observe that all states
have laws proscribing deceptive trade
practices.
124. Antitrust. The antitrust laws,
particularly Sections 1 and 2 of the
Sherman Act, as well as Section 5 of the
FTC Act, protect competition in all
sectors of the economy where the
antitrust agencies have jurisdiction.
When challenged as anticompetitive
under the antitrust laws, the types of
conduct and practices prohibited under
the Title II Order would likely be
evaluated under the ‘‘rule of reason,’’
which amounts to a consumer welfare
test. The Communications Act includes
an antitrust savings clause, so the
antitrust laws apply with equal vigor to
entities regulated by the Commission.
Should the hypothetical anticompetitive
harms that proponents of Title II
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
imagine eventually come to pass,
application of the antitrust laws would
address those harms.
125. Section 1 of the Sherman Act
bars contracts, combinations, or
conspiracies in restraint of trade,
making anticompetitive arrangements
illegal. If ISPs reached horizontal
agreements to unfairly block, throttle, or
discriminate against internet conduct or
applications, these agreements likely
would be per se illegal under the
antitrust laws. EFF argues that the single
entity doctrine means that a verticallyintegrated ISP could collude with its
affiliated content arm without fear of the
antitrust laws. This argument is
inapposite, however, because such a
claim against a vertically-integrated ISP
would likely be based on Section 2 of
the Sherman Act under an attempted
monopolization theory, rather than as a
Section 1 collusion claim. Section 2 of
the Sherman Act, which applies if a
firm possesses or has a dangerous
probability of achieving monopoly
power, prohibits exclusionary conduct,
which can include refusals to deal and
exclusive dealing, tying arrangements,
and vertical restraints. Section 2 makes
it unlawful for a vertically integrated
ISP to anticompetitively favor its
content or services over unaffiliated
edge providers’ content or services.
Treble damages are available under both
Section 1 and Section 2. We note that
FTC enforcement of Section 5 is broader
and would apply in the absence of
monopoly power.
126. Most of the examples of net
neutrality violations discussed in the
Title II Order could have been
investigated as antitrust violations.
Madison River Communications
blocked access to VoIP to foreclose
competition to its telephony business;
an antitrust case would have focused on
whether the company was engaged in
anticompetitive foreclosure to preserve
any monopoly power it may have had
over telephony. Whether one regards
Comcast’s behavior toward BitTorrent as
blocking or throttling, it could have
been pursued either as an antitrust or
consumer protection case. The
Commission noted that BitTorrent’s
service allowed users to view video that
they might otherwise have to purchase
through Comcast’s Video on Demand
service—a claim that could be
considered an anticompetitive
foreclosure claim under antitrust.
Comcast also failed to disclose this
network management practice and
initially denied that it was engaged in
any throttling—potentially unfair or
deceptive acts or practices. If an ISP that
also sells video services degrades the
speed or quality of competing ‘‘Over the
PO 00000
Frm 00029
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
7879
Top’’ video services (such as Netflix),
that conduct could be challenged as
anticompetitive foreclosure.
127. Among the benefits of the
antitrust laws over public utility
regulation are (1) the rule of reason
allows a balancing of pro-competitive
benefits and anti-competitive harms; (2)
the case-by-case nature of antitrust
allows for the regulatory humility
needed when dealing with the dynamic
internet; (3) the antitrust laws focus on
protecting competition; and (4) the same
long-practiced and well-understood
laws apply to all internet actors.
128. Reasonableness. The unilateral
conduct that is covered by Section 2 of
the Sherman Act would be evaluated
under a standard similar to the rule of
reason applicable to conduct governed
by Section 1, ‘‘an all-encompassing
inquiry, paying close attention to the
consumer benefits and downsides of the
challenged practice based on the facts at
hand.’’ We believe that such an inquiry
will strike a better balance in protecting
the openness of the internet and
continuing to allow the ‘‘permissionless
innovation’’ that made the internet such
an important part of the modern U.S.
economy, as antitrust uses a welfare
standard defined by economic analysis
shaped by a significant body of
precedent. Compare this to the Internet
Conduct Standard, which would
examine a variety of considerations
broader than consumer welfare, as well
as factors yet to be determined.
129. The case-by-case, contentspecific analysis established by the rule
of reason will allow new innovative
business arrangements to emerge as part
of the ever-evolving internet ecosystem.
New arrangements that harm consumers
and weaken competition will run afoul
of the Sherman Act, and successful
plaintiffs will receive treble damages.
The FTC and DOJ can also bring
enforcement actions in situations where
private plaintiffs are unable or
unwilling to do so. New arrangements
benefiting consumers, like so many
internet innovations over the last
generation, will be allowed to continue,
as was the case before the imposition of
Title II utility-style regulation of ISPs.
130. We reject commenters’ assertions
that the case-by-case nature of antitrust
enforcement makes it inherently flawed.
A case-by-case approach minimizes the
costs of overregulation, including
tarring all ISPs with the same brush, and
reduces the risk of false positives when
regulation is necessary. We believe the
Commission’s bright-line and internet
conduct rules are more likely to inhibit
innovation before it occurs, whereas
antitrust enforcement can adequately
remedy harms should they occur. As
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
7880
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
such, we reject the argument that
innovation is best protected by ex ante
rules and command-and-control
government regulation. Further, while a
handful of ISPs are large and vertically
integrated with content producers, most
ISPs are small companies that have no
leverage in negotiations with large edge
providers, which include some of the
most valuable companies in the world.
Regulating these companies is
unnecessarily harmful. The antitrust
laws can be tailored to the ISP’s
circumstances. We reject as
fundamentally speculative claims that
significantly different behavior is likely
from entities that were subject to
antitrust suits, as compared to those that
have not yet been—but still could be—
subject to such suits, or based on the
theory that antitrust authorities are
likely to negotiate materially different
resolutions even for similarly situated
entities or circumstances.
131. Moreover, the case-by-case
analysis, coupled with the rule of
reason, allows for innovative
arrangements to be evaluated based on
their real-world effects, rather than a
regulator’s ex ante predictions. Such an
approach better fits the dynamic
internet economy than the top-down
mandates imposed by Title II. Further,
the antitrust laws recognize the
importance of protecting innovation.
Indeed, the FTC has pursued several
cases in recent years where its theory of
harm was decreased innovation.
Accordingly, we believe that antitrust
law can sufficiently protect innovation,
which is a matter of particular
importance for the continued
development of the internet. Some
commenters argue that antitrust law is
more limited in scope than the rules in
the Title II Order, antitrust enforcement
necessarily takes place after some harm
has already occurred, and proving an
antitrust violation can be expensive and
time-consuming. However, with a body
of established and evolving precedent,
the FTC’s antitrust enforcement is factbased, flexible and applicable to
internet-related markets before the Title
II Order. We find that the antitrust
framework will strike a better balance
by protecting competition and
consumers while providing industry
with greater regulatory certainty. We
also find that the combination of the
transparency rule, ISP commitments,
and their enforcement by the FTC
sufficiently address the argument made
by several commenters that antitrust
moves too slowly and is too expensive
for many supposed beneficiaries of
regulation.
132. Additionally, the existence of
antitrust law deters much potential
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
anticompetitive conduct before it
occurs, and where it occurs offers
recoupment through damages to harmed
competitors. Some commenters have
cast doubt on the effectiveness of ex
post enforcement, preferring ex ante
rules. Yet as the FTC staff noted in its
comments, this is a false dichotomy.
‘‘Effective rule of law requires both
appropriate standards—whether
established by common law court,
Congress in statute, or by an agency in
rules—and active enforcement of those
standards.’’ Even the ‘‘bright line’’ rules
in the Title II Order contain an
exception for ‘‘reasonable network
management.’’ An ISP accused of
violating those rules would be the
subject of an ex post FCC enforcement
action. The FCC would have to
determine ex post whether a challenged
practice constituted technical network
management or not.
133. Moreover, economic research has
demonstrated that the threat of antitrust
enforcement deters anticompetitive
actions. Block et al. find that an increase
in the likelihood of antitrust
enforcement in the U.S. has a significant
effect on lowering prices to consumers.
Similarly it has been found that
countries with vigorous antitrust
statutes and enforcement, such as the
United States, reduce the effects of
anticompetitive behavior when it does
occur. There is also evidence that firms,
once they have been subject to an
enforcement action, are less likely to
violate the antitrust laws in the future.
Overall, we have confidence that the use
of antitrust enforcement to protect
competition in the broadband internet
service provider market will ensure that
consumers continue to reap the benefits
of that competition. We conclude that
the light-touch approach that we adopt
today, in combination with existing
antitrust and consumer protection laws,
more than adequately addresses
concerns about internet openness,
particularly as compared to the rigidity
of Title II. Some commenters have
raised issues about the feasibility of
antitrust as applied to some potential
harms. CompTIA and OTI claim that the
unilateral refusal to deal and essential
facilities cases are more difficult to
bring after Verizon Commc’ns, Inc. v.
Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, 540 U.S.
398 (2004) and Pacific Bell Tel. Co. v.
linkLine Commc’ns, Inc., 555 U.S. 438
(2009). To the extent these commenters
are correct, the transparency rule and
FTC enforcement of the commitments
(based on Section 5 of the FTC’s Act
broader reach than antitrust) remain to
protect the openness of the internet, and
PO 00000
Frm 00030
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
the shifts in antitrust doctrine do not
support the imposition of Title II.
134. Focus on protecting competition.
One of the benefits of antitrust law is its
strong focus on protecting competition
and consumers. If a particular practice
benefits consumers, antitrust law will
not condemn it. The fact that antitrust
law protects competition means that it
also protects other qualities that
consumers value. ‘‘[The] assumption
that competition is the best method of
allocating resources in a free market
recognizes that all elements of a
bargain—quality, service, safety, and
durability—and not just the immediate
cost, are favorably affected by the free
opportunity to select among alternative
offers.’’ The market competition that
antitrust law preserves will protect
values such as free expression, to the
extent that consumers value free
expression as a service attribute and are
aware of how their ISPs’ actions affect
free expression. The lack of evidence of
harms to free expression on the internet
also bolsters our belief that Title II is
unnecessary to protect social values that
are not the focus of antitrust. The
anecdotes of harms to internet openness
cited by supporters of the Title II Order
almost exclusively concern business
decisions regarding network
management, rather than being aimed at
or impacting political expression. In any
case, the transparency rule and the ISP
commitments backed up by FTC
enforcement are targeted to preserving
free expression, particularly the noblocking commitment. Therefore, we
believe that the argument that antitrust
law does not consider non-economic
factors such as free expression and
diversity fails to support Title II
regulation.
135. Finally, applying antitrust
principles to ISP conduct is consistent
with longstanding economic and legal
principles that cover all sectors of the
economy, including the entire internet
ecosystem. Applying the same body of
law to ISPs, edge providers, and all
internet actors avoids the regulatory
distortions of Title II, which ‘‘impos[ed]
asymmetric behavioral regulations . . .
on broadband ISPs under the banner of
protecting internet openness, but le[ft]
internet edge providers free to threaten
or engage in the same types of behavior
prohibited to ISPs free of any ex ante
constraints.’’ Our decision today to
return to light-touch Title I regulation
and the backstop of generally-applicable
antitrust and consumer protection law
‘‘help[s] to ensure a level, technologyneutral playing field’’ for the whole
internet.
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
D. Restoring the Information Service
Classification Is Lawful and Necessary
136. The Commission has the legal
authority to return to the classification
of broadband internet access service as
an ‘‘information service.’’ The Supreme
Court made clear when affirming the
Commission’s original information
service classification of cable modem
service that Congress ‘‘delegated to the
Commission authority to execute and
enforce the Communications Act, as
well as prescribe the rules and
regulations necessary in the public
interest to carry out the provisions.’’
This delegation includes the legal
authority to interpret the definitional
provisions of the Communications Act.
Nothing in the record meaningfully
contests this fundamental point. Relying
on that authority, we change course
from the Title II Order and restore the
information service classification of
broadband internet access service,
which represents the best interpretation
of the Act. We reject arguments against
reclassification based on alleged
shortcomings in the justification for
changing course provided in the
Internet Freedom NPRM given that we
fully explain here our rationale for
revisiting the Title II Order’s
classification of broadband internet
access service. As discussed above, this
action is supported by the text,
structure, and history of the Act, the
nature of ISP offerings, judicial and
Commission precedent, and the public
policy consequences flowing from
reclassification. For this reason, and for
those set forth more fully in Section III
above, we reject claims that an
information service classification is
unambiguously precluded. Such
assertions are contrary to our
interpretation of the statutory language
and our application of it to the facts
before us and also find no support in the
relevant court precedent addressing
prior classification decisions, which
either affirmed an information service
classification or affirmed the recent
telecommunications service
classification as merely a permissible
interpretation of ambiguous statutory
language. In making these arguments,
commenters do not dispute the
Commission’s general authority to
interpret and apply the Act, but merely
present arguments regarding the
reasonableness or permissibility of
interpreting or applying the Act in
particular ways.
137. An agency of course may decide
to change course, and such a decision is
not, as some commenters suggest,
inherently suspect. The Supreme Court
has observed that there is ‘‘no basis in
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
the Administrative Procedure Act or in
our opinions for a requirement that all
agency change be subjected to more
searching review. . . . [I]t suffices that
the new policy is permissible under the
statute, that there are good reasons for
it, and that the agency believes it to be
better, which the conscious change of
course adequately indicates.’’ Relevant
precedent holds that we need only
‘‘examine the relevant data and
articulate a satisfactory explanation for
[our] action,’’ a duty we fully satisfy
here. The ‘‘possibility of drawing two
inconsistent conclusions from the
evidence does not prevent an
administrative agency’s finding from
being supported by substantial
evidence.’’ As such, we reject arguments
that reclassification must be premised
on changed factual circumstances or
preceded by a significant gap in time.
Rather, we are ‘‘entitled to assess
administrative records and evaluate
priorities’’ in light of our current policy
judgments. As the Court recognized in
Brand X, ‘‘in Chevron itself, the Court
deferred to an agency interpretation that
was a recent reversal of agency policy.’’
The USTelecom decision supports our
understanding of the relevant legal
standard, affirming the Title II Order’s
reclassification of broadband internet
access service irrespective of whether
any facts had changed.
138. Such a change in course can be
justified on a variety of possible
grounds. The Supreme Court observed
in Brand X that ‘‘the agency . . . must
consider varying interpretations and the
wisdom of its policy on a continuing
basis, for example in response to . . . a
change in administrations.’’ In addition,
if an agency’s predictions ‘‘prove
erroneous, the Commission will need to
reconsider’’ the associated regulatory
actions ‘‘in accordance with its
continuing obligation to practice
reasoned decision-making.’’ In short, the
Commission’s reasoned determination
today that classifying broadband
internet access service as an information
service is superior both as a matter of
textual interpretation and public policy
suffices to support the change in
direction—even absent any new facts or
changes in circumstances. But even
assuming such new facts were
necessary, the record provides several
other sufficient and independent bases
for our decision to revisit the
classification of broadband internet
access service.
139. For example, we find that the
Title II Order’s regulatory predictions
have not been borne out. Although
purporting to adopt a ‘light-touch’
regulatory framework for broadband
internet access service, this view of the
PO 00000
Frm 00031
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
7881
Title II Order’s action faced skepticism
at the time, and we find those concerns
confirmed in practice. For example, the
Wireless Telecommunications Bureau
initiated inquiries into wireless ISPs’
sponsored data and zero-rated offerings,
leading to a report casting doubt on the
legality of certain types of such
offerings. That report was later
retracted. And the Commission
proceeded, in the wake of the
reclassification in the Title II Order, to
adopt complex and highly prescriptive
privacy regulations for broadband
internet access service, which
ultimately were disapproved by
Congress under the Congressional
Review Act. The amorphous and
potentially wide-ranging implications of
the Title II-based regulatory framework
have hindered (or will likely hinder)
marketplace innovation, as the record
here indicates and as one logically
would expect. We thus reject the
suggestion that the Title II Order yielded
‘‘legal and economic certainty.’’ That
certain specific steps eventually were
rolled back is no cure—rather, those
initial actions provide cause for
significant concerns that the regulatory
framework adopted in the Title II Order
would be anything but ‘‘light-touch’’
over time. Given the evidence that the
Title II-based framework prompted
additional regulatory action and was not
living up to its ‘‘light-touch’’ label, we
disagree with claims that ‘‘[t]here has
been no material change of
circumstance since the adoption of the’’
Title II Order, or that the shortcomings
inherent in the Title II approach could
be addressed adequately through minor
adjustments to the rules adopted in the
Title II Order.
140. Further, we are not persuaded
that there were reasonable reliance
interests in the Title II Order that
preclude our revisiting the classification
of broadband internet access service.
Contrary to Twilio’s assertion that
bright-line rules are over a decade old,
we note that the Commission did not
establish any rules until 2010—just
seven years ago—and did not establish
enforceable bright-line rules until
2015—just two years ago. Assertions in
the record regarding absolute levels of
edge investment do not meaningfully
attempt to attribute particular portions
of that investment to any reliance on the
Title II Order. Nor are we persuaded that
such reliance would have been
reasonable in any event, given the
lengthy prior history of information
service classification of broadband
internet access service, which we are
simply restoring here after the brief
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
7882
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
period of departure initiated by the Title
II Order.
141. ‘‘[A]n agency literally has no
power to act . . . unless and until
Congress confers power upon it.’’ And
so our role is to achieve the outcomes
Congress instructs, invoking the
authorities that Congress has given us—
not to assume that Congress must have
given us authority to address any
problems the Commission identifies.
However, rather than looking to
Congress to address its statutory
authority after the 2010 Comcast
decision, the Commission instead
attempted increasingly-regulatory
approaches under existing statutory
provisions, culminating in the Title II
Order’s application of a legal regime
that was ill-suited for broadband
internet access service. Returning to the
Commission’s historically sound
approach to interpreting and applying
the Act to broadband internet access
service corrects what we see as
shortcomings in how the Commission,
in the recent past, conceptualized its
role in this context.
142. We also conclude that the
Commission should have been
cautioned against reclassifying
broadband internet access service as a
telecommunications service in 2015
because doing so involved ‘‘laying claim
to extravagant statutory power over the
national economy while at the same
time strenuously asserting that the
authority claimed would render the
statute ‘unrecognizable to the Congress
that designed’ it.’’ Such interpretations
‘‘typically [are] greet[ed] . . . with a
measure of skepticism’’ by courts, and
we believe they should be by the
Commission, as well. We rely on these
principles to inform what interpretation
constitutes the best reading of the Act
independent of any broader legal
implications that potentially could
result from such considerations. Thus,
although the separate opinions in the
denial of rehearing en banc in
USTelecom debated the application of
such principles here—including with
respect to issues of agency deference
and the permissibility of the
Commission’s prior classification—we
need not and do not reach such broader
issues. As relevant here, the DC Circuit
in Verizon observed that ‘‘regulation of
broadband internet providers’’—there,
rules that required per se common
carriage—‘‘certainly involves decisions
of great ‘economic and political
significance.’ ’’ That seems at least as apt
a description of the Title II Order
decision classifying broadband internet
access service as a common carrier
telecommunications as one adopting
rules compelling the service to be
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
offered in a manner that is per se
common carriage. In particular, the Title
II Order recognized that classification of
broadband internet access service as a
telecommunications service would,
absent forbearance, subject the service
and its providers to a panoply of duties
and requirements ill-suited to
broadband internet access service. Thus,
not only did reclassification involve
what we see as a claim of extravagant
statutory power, but the Commission
found that much of the resulting power
was not sensibly applied to broadband
internet access service—a view we
believe also would be held by Congress
itself. Restoring the information service
classification that applied for nearly two
decades before the Title II Order does
not require any claim by the
Commission of extravagant statutory
power over broadband internet access
service and eliminates the anomaly that
ill-fitting Title II regulation would apply
by default to broadband internet access
service. These considerations thus lend
support to our decision to reclassify
broadband internet access service as an
information service.
E. Effects on Regulatory Structures
Created by the Title II Order
143. In this section, we clarify the
regulatory effects of today’s
reinstatement of broadband internet
access service as a Title I ‘‘information
service’’ on other regulatory frameworks
affected or imposed by the Title II
Order, including the effects on: (1)
Internet traffic exchange arrangements;
(2) the Title II Order’s forbearance
framework; (3) privacy; (4) wireline
broadband infrastructure; (5) wireless
broadband infrastructure; (6) universal
service; (7) jurisdiction and preemption;
and (8) disability access. We do not
intend for today’s classification to affect
ISPs’ obligations under the
Communications Assistance for Law
Enforcement Act, the Foreign
Intelligence Surveillance Act, or the
Electronic Communications Privacy Act.
No commenter identifies any such effect
of reclassification, nor does such a
change appear to have justified the
classification decision in the Title II
Order. We also are not persuaded that
our classification decision will itself
have material negative consequences as
it relates to safe harbor protections for
ISPs under the Digital Millennium
Copyright Act (DMCA). Our actions here
return to the analysis in Brand X and
other pre-2015 classification decisions
and the associated successful regulatory
framework, and we are not persuaded
that the DMCA would apply materially
differently now so as to render the
regulatory framework for broadband
PO 00000
Frm 00032
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
internet access service less successful
today.
1. Ending Title II Regulation of Internet
Traffic Exchange
144. The Title II Order applied, for the
first time, the requirements of Title II to
internet traffic exchange ‘‘by an edge
provider . . . with the broadband
provider’s network.’’ OTI’s argument
that internet traffic exchange was not
classified as a Title II service is
unpersuasive. The Title II Order did not
subject internet traffic exchange to Title
II obligations but, as OTI acknowledges,
interpreted broadband internet access
services to include internet traffic
exchange between an ISP and an edge
provider or its transit provider as ‘‘a
portion’’ of the service, or alternatively
as used ‘‘for and in connection with’’
that service. In doing so, the Title II
Order applied certain Title II
requirements to these internet traffic
exchange arrangements. We make clear
that as a result of our decision to restore
the longstanding classification of
broadband internet access service as an
information service, internet traffic
exchange arrangements are no longer
subject to Title II and its attendant
obligations. We thus return internet
traffic exchange to the longstanding free
market framework under which the
internet grew and flourished for
decades.
145. Background. As the Title II Order
acknowledges, the market for internet
traffic exchange between ISPs and edge
providers or their intermediaries
‘‘historically has functioned without
significant Commission oversight.’’ We
disagree with assertions that
withdrawing from regulation of
interconnection agreements would
represent a break with longstanding
Commission precedent. The
Commission made clear in the Open
Internet Order that it did not intend the
open internet rules ‘‘to affect existing
arrangements for network
interconnections, including existing
paid peering arrangements.’’ For many
years, both ISPs and edge providers
largely paid third-party backbone
service providers for transit, and
backbone providers connected upstream
until they reached Tier 1 backbone
service providers which provided access
to the full internet. In recent years,
particularly with the rise of online
video, edge providers increasingly used
CDNs and direct interconnection with
ISPs, rather than transit, to increase the
quality of their service. At the same
time, ISPs have increasingly built or
acquired their own backbone services,
allowing them to interconnect with
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
other networks without paying for thirdparty transit services.
146. Notwithstanding these
developments, but in line with other
aspects of the Title II Order seeking to
extend the Commission’s regulatory
authority, the Commission seized on a
handful of anecdotes to extend utilitystyle regulation to internet traffic
exchange arrangements. The Title II
Order applied eight different sections of
Title II, including Sections 201, 202,
and 208, to traffic exchange between
ISPs and edge providers or their
intermediaries. We reject the argument
that this application of Title II, which
includes potential Commission
mandates ‘‘to establish physical
connections with other carriers, to
establish through routes and charges
applicable thereto and the divisions of
such charges, and to establish and
provide facilities and regulations for
operating such through routes,’’ was
light-touch, measured regulation.
Although the Title II Order did not
apply the bright-line rules to internet
traffic exchange, it stated that the
Commission would be ‘‘available to hear
disputes regarding arrangements for the
exchange of traffic with a broadband
internet access provider raised under
Sections 201 and 202 on a case-by-case
basis.’’ The Commission did not
articulate specific criteria that it would
apply when hearing such disputes.
147. Deregulating Internet Traffic
Exchange. Today, we return to the preTitle II Order status quo by classifying
broadband internet access service as an
information service and, in doing so,
reverse that Order’s extension of Title II
authority to internet traffic exchange
arrangements. As was the case before
the Title II Order, we retain subjectmatter jurisdiction over internet traffic
exchange under Title I, to the extent
such exchange arrangements are ‘‘wire’’
or ‘‘radio communications.’’ There is no
dispute that ISPs, backbone transit
providers, and large edge providers are
sophisticated, well-capitalized
businesses. Indeed, the Title II Order
acknowledged as much, and refused to
impose ‘‘prescriptive rules’’ or even
‘‘draw policy conclusions concerning
new paid internet traffic arrangements.’’
Notwithstanding these
acknowledgments, the Title II Order cast
a shadow on new arrangements in this
sector by applying a range of common
carrier requirements to internet traffic
exchange.
148. We believe that applying Title II
to internet traffic exchange
arrangements was unnecessary and is
likely to unduly inhibit competition and
innovation. As the court in USTelecom
observed, the Title II Order’s oversight
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
of interconnection was premised on the
concern that ISPs could evade the
restrictions imposed via regulation of
the ‘‘last mile’’ through actions taken in
connection with internet
interconnection arrangements. Here,
however, we conclude that Title II
regulation and conduct rules are not
warranted even as to the ‘‘last mile.’’
The Title II Order itself recognized that
the need for intervention in matters of
internet interconnection was less certain
than its conclusions regarding ISP
actions in the ‘‘last mile.’’ Against that
backdrop, along with our finding that
Commission regulation of ISP conduct
in the ‘‘last mile’’ is unwarranted, we
see no grounds for finding that Title II
regulation of internet traffic exchange is
necessary here. And absent Title II as a
hook for regulation of internet traffic
exchange, we can identify no other
source of statutory authority to impose
market-wide prophylactic regulation on
these arrangements. To the extent we
have previously proposed conditions on
internet traffic exchange activities in the
context of specific mergers, those
conditions were based on the
circumstances of specific entities in
specific transactions and were agreed to
by those entities to facilitate a proposed
merger. Those conditions were not,
however, predicated on any statutory
provision giving the Commission
general authority to engage in
prophylactic regulation of all
interconnection arrangements.
149. Instead, we find that freeing
internet traffic exchange arrangements
from burdensome government
regulation, and allowing market forces
to discipline this emerging and
competitive market is the better course.
It is telling that, in the absence of Title
II regulation, the cost of internet transit
fell over 99 percent on a cost-permegabit basis from 2005 to 2015. We do
not rely on transit pricing alone, but
consider it in combination with the
other factors discussed in this section,
and thus reject as inapposite claims that
transit pricing alone is an inadequate
way of evaluating internet traffic
exchange. Further, we find that even
those commenters that insist that ISPs
wield undue power in the
interconnection market have offered no
evidence that ISPs generally charge
supra-competitive prices for internet
traffic exchange arrangements.
Moreover, we reject the proposition that
prior examples of settlement-free
peering necessarily mean that a transit
price above zero is inherently anti- or
supra-competitive. While the move to
paid peering may affect the bottom line
of Tier 1 transit providers, those effects
PO 00000
Frm 00033
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
7883
cannot justify ex ante regulation unless
they are anti-competitive and harm end
users. The record is devoid of evidence
of consumer harm in this regard since
the resolution of the Netflix congestion
issues in 2014. Indeed, the new case-bycase dispute process has gone unused,
even as OVDs—which ISPs presumably
might view as competitors to affiliated
video programming products or
services—have proliferated. Moreover,
contrary to these unsubstantiated claims
of harm, we find that there are
substantial pro-competitive and proconsumer benefits to alternative internet
traffic exchange arrangements. Because
we conclude that this is the wiser
course, we reject comments asserting
that a dispute resolution process is
needed.
150. We welcome the growth of
alternative internet traffic exchange
arrangements, including direct
interconnection, CDNs, and other
innovative efforts. All parties appear to
agree that direct interconnection has
benefited consumers by reducing
congestion, increasing speeds, and
housing content closer to consumers,
and allowed ISPs to better manage their
networks. CDNs play a similar role. We
believe that market dynamics, not Title
II regulation, allowed these diverse
arrangements to thrive. Our decision to
reclassify broadband internet access
service as an information service, and to
remove Title II utility-style regulation
from internet traffic exchange, will spur
further investment and innovation in
this market. Returning to the pre-Title II
Order light-touch framework will also
eliminate the asymmetrical regulatory
treatment of parties to internet traffic
exchange arrangements. As NTCA
explains, the Title II Order imposed a
one-sided interconnection duty upon
last-mile ISPs—even though, especially
in rural areas, ‘‘many ISPs are a tiny
fraction of the size of upstream middle
mile and transit networks or content
and edge providers.’’ The record reflects
that the asymmetric regulation imposed
under the Title II Order unjustifiably
provided edge providers, many of whom
are sophisticated entities with
significant market power due to high
demand for their content, with
additional leverage in negotiating
interconnection. We anticipate that
eliminating one-sided regulation of
internet traffic exchange and restoring
regulatory parity among sophisticated
commercial entities will allow the
parties to more efficiently negotiate
mutually-acceptable arrangements to
meet end user demands for network
usage.
151. We find that present competitive
pressures in the market for internet
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
7884
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
traffic exchange mitigate the risk that an
ISP might block or degrade edge
provider traffic through arrangements
for internet traffic exchange sufficiently
to undermine the need for regulatory
oversight through Title II regulation. We
thus disagree with generalized
assertions by some commenters to the
contrary. In drawing this conclusion, we
recognize that the Commission
previously imposed internet
interconnection conditions in the
AT&T/DirecTV Order and Charter/TWC
Order to address claimed risks that the
merged entity could use internet
interconnection to disadvantage rivals,
particularly competing providers of
over-the-top video services. We decline
to draw judgments about the nature of
the market as a whole from individual
determinations made in the context of
particular merger orders. As an initial
matter, the Commission made these
determinations pursuant to its authority
to impose conditions on transfers of
licenses or authorizations. As noted
above, the Commission has identified
no broader general authority to impose
these conditions on the interconnection
market as a whole. In addition, those
orders were based on an analysis of
specific issues raised in those
adjudications and application of a
public-interest statutory standard that
differs from the competition-based
standard applied by the Department of
Justice’s Antitrust Division during
merger review. Further, those orders
were based on a narrowly-focused
analysis of specific issues raised in
those adjudications. As we explain
above, based on the record here, we
decline to repeat that finding of high
switching costs. Finally, because those
orders were adopted without the benefit
of notice-and-comment rulemaking, we
decline to make general inferences from
conditions contained in such
documents, when the voluminous
record submitted in this proceeding
persuades us that the interconnection
market is competitive. We thus are
unpersuaded that the actions taken in
the AT&T/DirecTV Order and Charter/
TWC Order should guide our decisions
here. Interconnection concerns
generally focus on the possibility that an
ISP could block or allow congestion on
paths used to deliver traffic to that ISP
as a way of harming rivals or extracting
unreasonable payments associated with
that interconnection. Edge providers
have a variety of options in deciding
how to deliver their content to ISPs,
including a large number of transit
providers, CDNs, and direct
interconnection. Edge providers also
can shift the path for their traffic in
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
response to congestion in real time. To
address the possibility that edge
providers could simply shift their traffic
away from a blocked or congested path,
it appears in most cases that the ISP
would need to engage in blocking or
allow congestion on essentially all paths
to its network, affecting all traffic to and
from the ISP’s customers. To the extent
that some theorize that an ISP might
harm rivals with particularly high
volumes of internet traffic through
actions taken with respect to a smaller
number of interconnection paths, we are
not persuaded that such large providers
of internet traffic would lack sufficient
leverage to achieve a reasonable
marketplace resolution, particularly
given the increased likelihood that such
a large source of internet traffic would
be highly valued by end-users with
which it could communicate directly
regarding any interconnection dispute.
In addition, although certain forms of
traffic might be particularly sensitive to
the quality of interconnection such that
some alternative interconnection paths
would be inferior, it is likely that
blocking or allowing degradation of a
substantial number of paths to the ISP
still would be necessary for such
conduct to effectively impact such
traffic given that the concerns in the
record center on large ISPs, that are
more likely than small ISPs to have
multiple viable interconnection paths.
Further, that is but one of many
considerations that would affect the
relative incentives and marketplace
leverage of the relevant ISP and
interconnecting network and/or edge
provider. The practical viability of such
a strategy thus depends in general on an
ISP’s willingness to undermine the
performance of all or virtually all
internet traffic to and from its
customers. An ISP’s incentive to take
such a step would involve a complex
marketplace evaluation requiring it to
account for the associated risk of
customer dissatisfaction. Although this
consideration alone does not necessarily
guarantee that no ISP ever would engage
in such conduct, we reject
interconnection-related concerns that
fail to meaningfully grapple with this
factor. Further, this factor must be
considered in conjunction with the
overlay of legal protections, such as
antitrust and consumer protection laws
discussed below. We find that these
marketplace dynamics are likely to
impede, if not preclude, any effort by an
ISP to harm a specific edge provider’s
traffic.
152. Insofar as certain commenters
contend that incidents such as Cogent’s
experience delivering Netflix traffic in
PO 00000
Frm 00034
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
2014 suggest otherwise, we note that the
origin of the Cogent-Netflix congestion
is disputed and that Cogent admitted to
de-prioritizing certain types of traffic for
the congestion. In any event, there is
ample evidence that major edge
providers, including Netflix, YouTube,
and other large OVDs, are some of the
‘‘most-loved’’ brands in the world. Their
reputations and the importance of
reputation to their business and brand
gives them significant incentive to
inform consumers and work to shape
consumer perceptions in the event of
any dispute with ISPs. This incentive
mitigates potential concerns that
consumers lack the knowledge and
ability to hold their ISPs accountable for
interconnection disputes. Further, as
NCTA explains, ‘‘the edge providers
that send enough traffic to impact
interconnection—e.g., Netflix, Google/
YouTube, Facebook, and Amazon—are
entities critical for a broadband provider
to meet its customers’ needs.’’ As
another commenter explains, edge
providers, including OVDs, are
complementary to ISPs’ broadband
business, and reducing the value of
these complementary products would
harm ISPs by reducing demand for their
services. For all of these reasons, we
find that market dynamics are likely to
mitigate the risk that ISPs will block,
degrade, or deprioritize specific edge
providers’ traffic.
153. In addition, if an ISP attempts to
block or degrade traffic in a manner that
is anti-competitive, such conduct may
give rise to actions by federal or state
agencies under antitrust or consumer
protection laws. Some commenters have
called for continued ex post regulation
of internet traffic exchange between
ISPs and transit or edge providers,
potentially under Title I, or disclosure
requirements. For the reasons discussed
here, we reject these arguments. As to
antitrust laws, antitrust authorities are
empowered to police anti-competitive
conduct by ISPs (conduct that would be
particularly salient in cases where ISP
competition was limited or
nonexistent). We reject the argument
that the Commission’s decision in the
Charter-Time Warner Cable Merger
Order compels us to apply Title II
regulation to interconnection for the
reasons discussed herein, infra Part
VI.A. In addition, the backstop of
generally-applicable consumer
protection laws continues to protect
consumers and edge providers. These
laws, particularly antitrust laws which
prevent certain refusals to deal, will also
protect small, rural ISPs which may face
difficulties interconnecting with edge
providers, transit providers, and larger
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
ISPs. Accordingly, assertions that
public-utility regulation of internet
traffic exchange arrangements is
necessary to allow consumers to reach
content of their choice are unpersuasive.
154. Even assuming that economic
incentives and antitrust and consumer
protection remedies may not prevent or
redress all potential harms in the
interconnection market, we find the
regulatory approach adopted in the Title
II Order fatally overbroad as it relates to
the interconnection concerns identified
in the record here. The Title II Order’s
legal basis for oversight of
interconnection depended on the
definition of broadband internet access
service to include traffic exchange and
the classification of that entire service as
a telecommunications service subject to
Title II—a classification that applied to
all ISPs, regardless of size or other
characteristics. Here, however, we have
already rejected the Title II Order’s
rationales for Title II regulation and
explained the harms that flow from that
regime. The record reveals that retaining
the Title II Order approach to
interconnection would be overbroad in
other ways, as well. The classification
decision in that Order applied to all
ISPs regardless of size, while the
concerns about ISPs in the record here
center on a few of the largest ISPs. The
Title II Order classification also applied
irrespective of the specific traffic being
carried, while some advocates of
interconnection oversight here express
particular concerns about certain
subsets of traffic, like video traffic.
Particularly given the marketplace
complexities associated with whether a
given ISP would, in fact, engage in
harmful conduct, we are not persuaded
that the inchoate interconnection
concerns identified in the record here
would justify retaining the Title II
Order’s approach to interconnection
with its sweeping, preemptive—and
harmful—resulting consequences.
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
2. Forbearance
155. As we have reinstated the
information service classification of
broadband internet access service, the
forbearance granted in the Title II Order
is now moot. We return to the pre-Title
II Order status quo and allow providers
voluntarily electing to offer broadband
transmission on a common carrier basis
to do so under the frameworks
established in the Wireline Broadband
Classification Order and the Wireless
Broadband Internet Access Order. We
also clarify that carriers are no longer
permitted to use the Title II Order
forbearance framework (i.e., no carrier
will be permitted to maintain, or newly
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
elect, the Title II Order forbearance
framework).
156. Prior to the Title II Order, some
facilities-based wireline carriers chose
to offer broadband transmission services
on a common carrier basis subject to the
full range of Title II requirements. In the
2005 Wireline Broadband Classification
Order, the Commission ruled that
broadband internet access was an
information service, but at the same
time permitted facilities-based wireline
carriers to voluntarily elect to offer the
transmission component of broadband
internet access service (often referred to
as digital subscriber line or DSL) on a
common carrier basis. Operators
choosing to offer broadband
transmission on a common carriage
basis could do so under tariff or could
use non-tariff arrangements. The
Commission permitted facilities-based
carriers to choose whether to offer
wireline broadband internet access
transmission as non-common carriage or
common carriage to ‘‘enable facilitiesbased wireline internet access providers
to maximize their ability to deploy
broadband internet access services and
facilities in competition with other
platform providers, under a regulatory
framework that provides all market
participants with the flexibility to
determine how best to structure their
business operations.’’ Generally, ISPs
that chose to elect common carrier
status were smaller carriers that served
‘‘rural, sparsely-populated areas’’ and
obtained significant benefits from the
provision of broadband transmission
services on a common carriage basis,
including the ability to participate in
common tariff arrangements via the
NECA pools and the availability of highcost universal service support.
157. We agree with NTCA and NECA
that the broadband transmission
services currently offered by rural LECs
under tariff differ substantially from the
broadband internet access services at
issue in this proceeding, and as such are
not impacted by our decision to
reclassify broadband internet access
service as an information service. The
term ‘‘wireline broadband internet
access service’’ refers to ‘‘a mass-market
retail service by wire that provides the
capability to transmit data to and
receive data from all or substantially all
internet endpoints, including any
capabilities that are incidental to and
enable the operation of the
communications service, but excluding
dial-up internet access service.’’
Broadband transmission services do not
provide end users with direct
connectivity to the internet backbone or
content, but instead enable data traffic
generated by end users to be transported
PO 00000
Frm 00035
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
7885
to an ISP’s Access Service Connection
Point over rural LEC local exchange
service facilities for subsequent
interconnection with the internet
backbone.
158. Carriers offering broadband
transmission service have never been
subject to the Title II Order forbearance
framework. The Title II Order
forbearance framework with respect to
broadband internet access service did
not encompass broadband transmission
services and permitted carriers to
voluntarily elect to offer transmission
services on a common carriage basis
pursuant to the Wireline Broadband
Classification Order. The Title II Order
made clear that broadband transmission
services would continue to be subject to
the full panoply of Title II obligations
(e.g., USF contributions), including
those from which the Commission
forbore from in the Title II Order. Thus,
only carriers that elected to cease
offering broadband transmission
services and instead offer broadband
internet access services (including a
transmission service component) were
subject to the Title II Order forbearance
framework (e.g., forbearance from USF
contributions applied to such carriers).
Over one hundred providers opted-into
the Title II Order forbearance framework
and in their letters to the Commission,
they noted that the transmission
component would only be provided as
part of the complete broadband internet
access service.
159. Today, we return to the pre-Title
II Order status quo and allow carriers to
elect to offer broadband transmission
services on a common carrier basis,
either pursuant to tariff or on a nontariffed basis. We find the reasoning in
the Wireline Broadband Classification
Order for offering these options
persuasive. Irrespective of the regulatory
classification of broadband internet
access services, the Commission has
continuously permitted facilities-based
wireline carriers to provide broadband
internet transmission services on a Title
II common carriage basis, with
substantial flexibility in deciding how
such services may be offered (i.e., on a
tariffed or non-tariffed basis). Providing
these options offers small carriers muchneeded regulatory certainty as they have
sought to deploy and maintain
broadband internet access services to
their customers. We reiterate that
broadband transmission services are not
impacted by our decision to reclassify
broadband internet access service as an
information service.
160. We clarify that carriers that
choose to offer transmission service on
a common carriage basis are, as under
the Wireline Broadband Classification
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
7886
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
Order, subject to the full set of Title II
obligations, to the extent they applied
before the Title II Order. Similarly, a
wireless broadband internet access
provider may choose to offer the
transmission component as a
telecommunications service and the
transmission component of wireless
broadband internet access service as a
telecommunications service only if the
entity that provides the transmission
voluntarily undertakes to provide it
indifferently on a common carrier basis.
Such an offering is a common carrier
service subject to Title II. In addition, a
wireless broadband internet access
provider that chooses to offer the
telecommunications transmission
component as a telecommunications
service may also be subject to the
‘‘commercial mobile service’’ provisions
of the Act. Further, we clarify that those
carriers that had previously been
offering a broadband transmission
service (subject to the full panoply of
Title II regulations) and that elected to
instead offer broadband internet access
service after the Title II Order now will
be deemed to be offering an information
service. The Commission has never
allowed carriers offering broadband
transmission services on a common
carrier basis to opt in to the Title II
Order forbearance framework for those
transmission services. Carriers that
prefer light-touch regulation may elect
to offer broadband internet access
service as an information service.
Although WTA argues that allowing
rural LECs to opt into the forbearance
framework will ‘‘enable a much more
level competitive playing field in the
retail marketplace,’’ no other carriers are
subject to that framework, and we find
that allowing carriers to opt into the
forbearance framework will result in a
regulatory disparity. We therefore reject
WTA’s argument that the Commission
should continue to permit opting into
the Title II Order forbearance. To the
extent that other related issues are
raised in the record, we find that those
issues are better addressed in the
appropriate proceeding.
161. We also reject AT&T’s assertion
that the Commission should
conditionally forbear from all Title II
regulations as a preventive measure to
address the contingency that a future
Commission might seek to reinstate the
Title II Order. Although AT&T explains
that ‘‘conditional forbearance would
provide an extra level of insurance
against the contingency that a future,
politically motivated Commission might
try to reinstate a ‘common carrier’
classification,’’ we see no need to
address the complicated question of
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
prophylactic forbearance and find such
extraordinary measures unnecessary.
3. Returning Broadband Privacy
Authority to the FTC
162. By reinstating the information
service classification of broadband
internet access service, we return
jurisdiction to regulate broadband
privacy and data security to the Federal
Trade Commission (FTC), the nation’s
premier consumer protection agency
and the agency primarily responsible for
these matters in the past. Restoring FTC
jurisdiction over ISPs will enable the
FTC to apply its extensive privacy and
data security expertise to provide the
uniform online privacy protections that
consumers expect and deserve.
163. Historically, the FTC protected
the privacy of broadband consumers,
policing every online company’s
privacy practices consistently and
initiating numerous enforcement
actions. In fact, the FTC has ‘‘brought
over 500 enforcement actions protecting
the privacy and security of consumer
information, including actions against
ISPs and against some of the biggest
companies in the internet ecosystem.’’
When the Commission reclassified
broadband internet access service as a
common carriage telecommunications
service in 2015, however, that action
stripped FTC authority over ISPs
because the FTC is prohibited from
regulating common carriers. The effect
of this decision was to shift
responsibility for regulating broadband
privacy to the Commission. And in lieu
of an even playing field, the
Commission adopted sector-specific
rules that deviated from the FTC’s
longstanding framework. In March 2017,
Congress voted under the Congressional
Review Act (CRA) to disapprove the
Commission’s 2016 Privacy Order,
which prevents us from adopting rules
in substantially the same form.
164. Undoing Title II reclassification
restores jurisdiction to the agency with
the most experience and expertise in
privacy and data security, better reflects
congressional intent, and creates a level
playing field when it comes to internet
privacy. Restoring FTC authority to
regulate broadband privacy and data
security also fills the consumer
protection gap created by the Title II
Order when it stripped the FTC of
jurisdiction over ISPs. Consumers
expect information to be ‘‘treated
consistently across the internet
ecosystem and that their personal
information will be subject to the same
framework, in all contexts.’’ Under the
FTC’s technology neutral approach to
privacy regulation, consumers will have
the consistent level of protection across
PO 00000
Frm 00036
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
the internet ecosystem that they expect.
With over 100 years of experience, only
the FTC can apply consumer protection
rules consistently across industries. As
NTCA contends, the FTC has not only
the legal jurisdiction, but also the
subject matter expertise. In 2007, the
FTC issued a 167-page report that
delved into both the technical and legal
bases of the internet and how the law
approaches it. Moreover, the FTC has
been involved in numerous initiatives
that address consumer protection in the
broadband marketplace. The FTC’s
‘‘flexible, enforcement-focused
approach has enabled the agency to
apply strong consumer privacy and
security protections across a wide range
of changing technologies and business
models, without imposing unnecessary
or undue burdens on industry.’’
Moreover, the flexibility of the FTC’s
enforcement framework ‘‘allows room
for new business models that could
support expensive, next-generation
networks with revenue other than
consumers’ monthly bills.’’ The FTC has
already ‘‘delivered the message to
entities in a range of fields—retailers,
app developers, data brokers, health
companies, financial institutions, thirdparty service providers, and others—
that they need to provide consumers
with strong privacy and data security
protections.’’ The same approach should
apply to ISPs. We also observe that ISPs
are not uniquely positioned with respect
to their insight into customers’ private
browsing behavior. As the FTC found in
2012, ‘‘ISPs are just one type of large
platform provider that may have access
to all or nearly all of a consumer’s
online activity. Like ISPs, operating
systems and browsers may be in a
position to track all, or virtually all, of
a consumer’s online activity to create
highly detailed profiles.’’ And only the
FTC operates on a national level across
industries, which is especially
important when regulating providers
that operate across state lines. In light of
the FTC’s decades of successful
experience, including its oversight of
ISP privacy practices prior to 2015, we
find arguments that we should decline
to reclassify to retain sector-specific
control of ISP privacy practices
unpersuasive. The FTC has previously
brought enforcement actions against
ISPs regarding internet access and
related issues. The FTC has also
‘‘brought enforcement actions in matters
involving access to content via
broadband and other internet access
services,’’ such as the FTC’s challenge to
the proposed AOL and Time Warner
merger, in part, over concern for
potential harm to consumers’ broadband
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
internet access. We also note that while
it may be true that the Commission itself
has longstanding privacy experience
with respect to traditional telephone
service providers, we disagree that this
history uniquely qualifies the
Commission to regulate the privacy
practices of ISPs or other online
providers, when prior to 2015, the
Commission did not, and indeed lacked
the authority to, regulate such
providers. We do not believe that
experience with traditional telephone
service providers necessarily translates
to experience or expertise with respect
to all communications providers. Some
commenters object that the FTC is not
suited to protect privacy on the internet,
citing the FTC’s narrower authority and
fewer resources than the Commission
and the absence of specific statutory
directive from Congress to the FTC to
regulate privacy. As discussed above,
these criticisms are unfounded.
Furthermore, the uncertainty related to
the Commission’s current authority over
broadband privacy regulation created by
the CRA resolution of disapproval also
weighs in favor of returning jurisdiction
to the FTC.
165. We also reject arguments that
rely on the Ninth Circuit panel decision
holding that the common carrier
exemption precludes FTC oversight of
non-common carriage activities of
common carriers. As the FCC’s amicus
letter explained in that case, the panel
decision erred by overlooking the
textual relationship between the statutes
governing the FTC’s and FCC’s
jurisdiction. We note that commenter
concerns focus not just on the FTC’s
privacy authority but its authority more
generally. We reject those arguments for
the reasons stated above. Consistent
with the Commission’s request, the
Ninth Circuit granted rehearing en banc
of the panel decision, and in doing so
it set aside the earlier panel opinion.
This en banc order means that the Title
II Order’s reclassification of broadband
internet access service serves as the only
current limit on the authority of the FTC
to oversee the conduct of internet
service providers. We note that at any
given time there always may be some
litigation pending somewhere in the
country challenging the scope or
validity of various laws—whether the
Communications Act, FTC Act, or state
consumer protection laws—that the FCC
might seek to rely on directly (in the
case of the Act) or indirectly (where
relying in part on the availability of
protections provided by other laws).
The Commission would be paralyzed if
it had to wait for all such litigation to
be resolved before it acted. Because the
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
panel decision has been set aside in FTC
v. AT&T Mobility, we do not view that
case as materially different than any
other such pending litigation—so we
likewise do not view it as necessary to
wait on the resolution of that case before
acting here. In light of these
considerations and the benefits of
reclassification, we find objections
based on FTC v. AT&T Mobility
insufficient to warrant a different
outcome.
4. Wireline Infrastructure
166. To the extent today’s
classification decision impacts the
deployment of wireline infrastructure,
we will address that topic in detail in
proceedings specific to those issues. The
importance of facilitating broadband
infrastructure deployment indicates that
our authority to address barriers to
infrastructure deployment warrants
careful review in the appropriate
proceedings. We disagree with
commenters who assert that Title II
classification is necessary to maintain
our authority to promote infrastructure
investment and broadband deployment.
Because the same networks are often
used to provide broadband and either
telecommunications or cable service, we
will take further action as is necessary
to promote broadband deployment and
infrastructure investment. Further, Title
I classification of broadband internet
access services is consistent with the
Commission’s broadband deployment
objectives, whereas the Title II
regulatory environment undermines the
very private investment and buildout of
broadband networks the Commission
seeks to encourage. Additionally, in the
twenty states and the District of
Columbia that have reverse-preempted
Commission jurisdiction over pole
attachments, those states rather than the
Commission are empowered to regulate
the pole attachment process.
167. We are resolute that today’s
decision not be misinterpreted or used
as an excuse to create barriers to
infrastructure investment and
broadband deployment. For example,
we caution pole owners not to use this
Order as a pretext to increase pole
attachment rates or to inhibit broadband
providers from attaching equipment—
and we remind pole owners of their
continuing obligation to offer ‘‘rates,
terms, and conditions [that] are just and
reasonable.’’ We will not hesitate to take
action where we identify barriers to
broadband infrastructure deployment.
We have been working diligently to
remove barriers to broadband
deployment and fully intend to
continue to do so.
PO 00000
Frm 00037
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
7887
5. Wireless Infrastructure
168. When the Commission first
classified wireless broadband internet
access as an information service in
2007, it emphasized that certain
statutory provisions in Section 224
(regarding pole attachments) and
332(c)(7) (local authority over zoning) of
the Act would continue to apply where
the same infrastructure was used to
provide a covered service (e.g., cable or
telecommunications service) as well as
wireless broadband internet access.
Section 224 gives cable television
systems and providers of
telecommunications services the right to
attach to utility poles of power and
telephone companies at regulated rates.
Section 332(c)(7) generally preserves
state and local authority over ‘‘personal
wireless service facilities’’ siting or
modification, but subjects that authority
to certain limitations. Among other
limitations, it provides that state or local
government regulation (1) ‘‘shall not
unreasonably discriminate among
providers of functionally equivalent
services,’’ (2) ‘‘shall not prohibit or have
the effect of prohibiting the provision of
personal wireless services’’ and (3) may
not regulate the siting of personal
wireless service facilities ‘‘on the basis
of the environmental effects of [RF]
emissions to the extent that such
facilities comply with the Commission’s
regulations concerning such emissions.’’
169. As to Section 224, the
Commission clarified in the Wireless
Broadband Internet Access Order that
where the same infrastructure would
provide ‘‘both telecommunications and
wireless broadband internet access
service,’’ the provisions of Section 224
governing pole attachments would
continue to apply to such infrastructure
used to provide both types of service.
The Commission similarly clarified that
Section 332(c)(7)(B) would continue to
apply to wireless broadband internet
access service where a wireless service
provider uses the same infrastructure to
provide its ‘‘personal wireless services’’
and wireless broadband internet access
service.
170. We reaffirm the Commission’s
interpretations regarding the application
of Sections 224 and 332(c)(7) to wireless
broadband internet access service here.
The Commission’s rationale from 2007,
that commingling services does not
change the fact that the facilities are
being used for the provisioning of
services within the scope of the
statutory provision, remains equally
valid today. This clarification will
alleviate concerns that wireless
broadband internet access providers not
face increased barriers to infrastructure
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
7888
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
deployment as a result of today’s
reclassification. This clarification also is
consistent with our commitment to
promote broadband deployment and
close the digital divide.
171. Although the wireless
infrastructure industry has changed
significantly since the adoption of the
Wireless Broadband Internet Access
Order, it remains the case that cell
towers and other forms of network
equipment can be used ‘‘for the
provision’’ of both personal wireless
services and wireless broadband
internet access on a commingled basis.
These communications facilities are
sometimes built by providers
themselves, but are increasingly being
deployed by third-parties who then offer
the use of these facilities to wireless
service providers for a variety of
services, including telecommunications
services and information services. To
remove any uncertainty, we clarify that
Section 332(c)(7) applies to facilities,
including DAS or small cells, deployed
and offered by third-parties for the
purpose of provisioning
communications services that include
personal wireless services. Consistent
with the statutory provisions and
Commission precedent, we consider
infrastructure that will be deployed for
the provision of personal wireless
services, including third-party facilities
such as neutral-host deployments, to be
‘‘facilities for the provision of personal
wireless services’’ and therefore subject
to Section 332(c)(7) as ‘‘personal
wireless service facilities’’ even where
such facilities also may be used for
broadband internet access services.
172. We reiterate our commitment to
expand broadband access, encourage
innovation and close the digital divide.
We will closely monitor developments
on broadband infrastructure deployment
and move quickly to address barriers in
a future proceeding if necessary.
6. Universal Service
173. The reclassification of consumer
and small business broadband access as
an information service does not affect or
alter the Commission’s existing
programs to support the deployment
and maintenance of broadband-capable
networks, i.e., the Connect America
Fund’s high-cost universal service
support mechanisms. As explained in
the USF/ICC Transformation Order, the
Commission has authority to ensure that
‘‘the national policy of promoting
broadband deployment and ubiquitous
access to voice telephony services is
fully realized’’ and require that ‘‘carriers
receiving support . . . offer broadband
capabilities to customers.’’ What
services a particular customer
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
subscribes to is irrelevant as long as
high-cost support is used to build and
maintain a network that provides both
voice and broadband internet access
service. Thus, the classification of
broadband internet access as an
information service does not change the
eligibility of providers of those services
to receive federal high-cost universal
service support.
174. Lifeline. We conclude that we
need not address concerns in the record
about the effect of our reclassification of
broadband internet access service as an
information service on the Lifeline
program at this time. In November 2017,
we adopted an NPRM in the Lifeline
proceeding (Lifeline NPRM) (83 FR
2075) in which we proposed limiting
Lifeline support to facilities-based
broadband service provided to a
qualifying low-income consumer over
the eligible telecommunication carrier’s
(ETC’s) voice- and broadband-capable
last-mile network, and sought comment
on discontinuing Lifeline support for
service provided over non-facilitiesbased networks, to advance our policy
of focusing Lifeline support to
encourage investment in voice- and
broadband-capable networks. As
explained in the Lifeline NPRM, we
‘‘believe the Commission has authority
under Section 254(e) of the Act to
provide Lifeline support to ETCs that
provide broadband service over
facilities-based broadband-capable
networks that support voice service’’
and that ‘‘[t]his legal authority does not
depend on the regulatory classification
of broadband internet access service
and, thus, ensures the Lifeline program
has a role in closing the digital divide
regardless of the regulatory
classification of broadband service.’’ We
thus find that today’s reinstatement of
the information service classification for
broadband internet access service does
not require us to address here our legal
authority to continue supporting
broadband internet access service in the
Lifeline program, as such concerns are
more appropriately addressed in the
ongoing Lifeline proceeding.
7. Preemption of Inconsistent State and
Local Regulations
175. We conclude that regulation of
broadband internet access service
should be governed principally by a
uniform set of federal regulations, rather
than by a patchwork that includes
separate state and local requirements.
Our order today establishes a calibrated
federal regulatory regime based on the
pro-competitive, deregulatory goals of
the 1996 Act. Allowing state and local
governments to adopt their own
separate requirements, which could
PO 00000
Frm 00038
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
impose far greater burdens than the
federal regulatory regime, could
significantly disrupt the balance we
strike here. Federal courts have
uniformly held that an affirmative
federal policy of deregulation is entitled
to the same preemptive effect as a
federal policy of regulation. In addition,
allowing state or local regulation of
broadband internet access service could
impair the provision of such service by
requiring each ISP to comply with a
patchwork of separate and potentially
conflicting requirements across all of
the different jurisdictions in which it
operates. Just as the Title II Order
promised to ‘‘exercise our preemption
authority to preclude states from
imposing regulations on broadband
service that are inconsistent’’ with the
federal regulatory scheme, we conclude
that we should exercise our authority to
preempt any state or local requirements
that are inconsistent with the federal
deregulatory approach we adopt today.
176. We therefore preempt any state
or local measures that would effectively
impose rules or requirements that we
have repealed or decided to refrain from
imposing in this order or that would
impose more stringent requirements for
any aspect of broadband service that we
address in this order. This includes any
state laws that would require the
disclosure of broadband internet access
service performance information,
commercial terms, or network
management practices in any way
inconsistent with the transparency rule
we adopt herein. Our transparency rule
is carefully calibrated to reflect the
information that consumers,
entrepreneurs, small businesses, and the
Commission needs to ensure a
functioning market for broadband
internet access services and to ensure
the Commission has sufficient
information to identify market-entry
barriers—all without unduly burdening
ISPs with disclosure requirements that
would raise the cost of service or
otherwise deter innovation within the
network. Among other things, we
thereby preempt any so-called
‘‘economic’’ or ‘‘public utility-type’’
regulations, including common-carriage
requirements akin to those found in
Title II of the Act and its implementing
rules, as well as other rules or
requirements that we repeal or refrain
from imposing today because they could
pose an obstacle to or place an undue
burden on the provision of broadband
internet access service and conflict with
the deregulatory approach we adopt
today. The terms ‘‘economic regulation’’
and ‘‘public utility-type regulation,’’ as
used here, are terms of art that the
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
Commission has used to include, among
other things, requirements that all rates
and practices be just and reasonable;
prohibitions on unjust or unreasonable
discrimination; tariffing requirements;
accounting requirements; entry and exit
restrictions; interconnection obligations;
and unbundling or network-access
requirements. We are not persuaded that
preemption is contrary to Section 706(a)
of the 1996 Act, 47 U.S.C. 1302(a),
insofar as that provision directs state
commissions (as well as this
Commission) to promote the
deployment of advanced
telecommunications capability. For one
thing, as discussed infra, we conclude
that Section 706 does not constitute an
affirmative grant of regulatory authority,
but instead simply provides guidance to
this Commission and the state
commissions on how to use any
authority conferred by other provisions
of federal and state law. For another,
nothing in this order forecloses state
regulatory commissions from promoting
the goals set forth in Section 706(a)
through measures that we do not
preempt here, such as by promoting
access to rights-of-way under state law,
encouraging broadband investment and
deployment through state tax policy,
and administering other generally
applicable state laws. Finally, insofar as
we conclude that Section 706’s goals of
encouraging broadband deployment and
removing barriers to infrastructure
investment are best served by
preempting state regulation, we find
that Section 706 supports (rather than
prohibits) the use of preemption here.
177. Although we preempt state and
local laws that interfere with the federal
deregulatory policy restored in this
order, we do not disturb or displace the
states’ traditional role in generally
policing such matters as fraud, taxation,
and general commercial dealings, so
long as the administration of such
general state laws does not interfere
with federal regulatory objectives. We
thus conclude that our preemption
determination is not contrary to Section
414 of the Act, which states that
‘‘[n]othing in [the Act] shall in any way
abridge or alter the remedies now
existing at common law or by statute.’’
Under this order, states retain their
traditional role in policing and
remedying violations of a wide variety
of general state laws. The record does
not reveal how our preemption here
would deprive states of their ability to
enforce any remedies that fall within the
purview of Section 414. In any case, a
general savings clause like Section 414
‘‘do[es] not preclude preemption where
allowing state remedies would lead to a
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
conflict with or frustration of statutory
purposes.’’ Indeed, the continued
applicability of these general state laws
is one of the considerations that
persuade us that ISP conduct regulation
is unnecessary here. Nor do we deprive
the states of any functions expressly
reserved to them under the Act, such as
responsibility for designating eligible
telecommunications carriers under
Section 214(e); exclusive jurisdiction
over poles, ducts, conduits, and rightsof-way when a state certifies that it has
adopted effective rules and regulations
over those matters under Section 224(c);
or authority to adopt state universal
service policies not inconsistent with
the Commission’s rules under Section
254. We find no basis in the record to
conclude that our preemption
determination would interfere with
states’ authority to address rights-of-way
safety issues. We note that we continue
to preempt any state from imposing any
new state universal service fund
contributions on broadband internet
access service. We appreciate the many
important functions served by our state
and local partners, and we fully expect
that the states will ‘‘continue to play
their vital role in protecting consumers
from fraud, enforcing fair business
practices, for example, in advertising
and billing, and generally responding to
consumer inquiries and complaints’’
within the framework of this order.
178. Legal Authority. We conclude
that the Commission has legal authority
to preempt inconsistent state and local
regulation of broadband internet access
service on several distinct grounds.
179. First, the U.S. Supreme Court
and other courts have recognized that,
under what is known as the
impossibility exception to state
jurisdiction, the FCC may preempt state
law when (1) it is impossible or
impracticable to regulate the intrastate
aspects of a service without affecting
interstate communications and (2) the
Commission determines that such
regulation would interfere with federal
regulatory objectives. Here, both
conditions are satisfied. Indeed, because
state and local regulation of the aspects
of broadband internet access service that
we identify would interfere with the
balanced federal regulatory scheme we
adopt today, they are plainly
preempted.
180. As a preliminary matter, it is
well-settled that internet access is a
jurisdictionally interstate service
because ‘‘a substantial portion of
internet traffic involves accessing
interstate or foreign websites.’’ Thus,
when the Commission first classified a
form of broadband internet access
service in the Cable Modem Order, it
PO 00000
Frm 00039
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
7889
recognized that cable internet service is
an ‘‘interstate information service.’’ Five
years later, the Commission reaffirmed
the jurisdictionally interstate nature of
broadband internet access service in the
Wireless Broadband Internet Access
Order. And even when the Title II Order
reclassified broadband internet access
service as a telecommunications service,
the Commission continued to recognize
that ‘‘broadband internet access service
is jurisdictionally interstate for
regulatory purposes.’’ The record
continues to show that broadband
internet access service is predominantly
interstate because a substantial amount
of internet traffic begins and ends across
state lines.
181. Because both interstate and
intrastate communications can travel
over the same internet connection (and
indeed may do so in response to a single
query from a consumer), it is impossible
or impracticable for ISPs to distinguish
between intrastate and interstate
communications over the internet or to
apply different rules in each
circumstance. Accordingly, an ISP
generally could not comply with state or
local rules for intrastate
communications without applying the
same rules to interstate
communications. We therefore reject the
view that the impossibility exception to
state jurisdiction does not apply because
some aspects of broadband internet
access service could theoretically be
regulated differently in different states.
Even if it were possible for New York to
regulate aspects of broadband service
differently from New Jersey, for
example, it would not be possible for
New York to regulate the use of a
broadband internet connection for
intrastate communications without also
affecting the use of that same
connection for interstate
communications. The relevant question
under the impossibility exception is not
whether it would be possible to have
separate rules in separate states, but
instead whether it would be feasible to
allow separate state rules for intrastate
communications while maintaining
uniform federal rules for interstate
communications. Thus, because any
effort by states to regulate intrastate
traffic would interfere with the
Commission’s treatment of interstate
traffic, the first condition for conflict
preemption is satisfied. OTI insists that
broadband service ‘‘can easily be
separated into interstate and intrastate’’
communications based on ‘‘the location
of the ISP.’’ In OTI’s view, if ‘‘the closest
ISP headend, tower, or other facility to
the customer’’ is in the same state as the
customer, then the customer’s internet
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
7890
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
communications are all intrastate. This
view misapprehends the end-to-end
analysis employed by the
Communications Act to distinguish
interstate and intrastate
communications, which looks to where
a communication ultimately originates
and terminates—such as the server
which hosts the content the consumer is
requesting—rather than to intermediate
steps along the way (such as the
location of the ISP). Indeed, OTI’s view
that a communication is intrastate
whenever the ‘‘last mile’’ facilities
between the customer and the
communications carrier are within the
same state would improperly deem
virtually all communications to be
intrastate, including interstate telephone
calls, contrary to long-settled precedent.
182. The second condition for the
impossibility exception to state
jurisdiction is also satisfied. For the
reasons explained above, we find that
state and local regulation of the aspects
of broadband internet access service that
we identify would interfere with the
balanced federal regulatory scheme we
adopt today.
183. Second, the Commission has
independent authority to displace state
and local regulations in accordance with
the longstanding federal policy of
nonregulation for information services.
For more than a decade prior to the
1996 Act, the Commission consistently
preempted state regulation of
information services (which were then
known as ‘‘enhanced services’’). When
Congress adopted the Commission’s
regulatory framework and its
deregulatory approach to information
services in the 1996 Act, it thus
embraced our longstanding policy of
preempting state laws that interfere with
our federal policy of nonregulation.
184. Multiple provisions enacted by
the 1996 Act confirm Congress’s
approval of our preemptive federal
policy of nonregulation for information
services. Section 230(b)(2) of the Act, as
added by the 1996 Act, declares it to be
‘‘the policy of the United States’’ to
‘‘preserve the vibrant and competitive
free market that presently exists for the
internet and other interactive computer
services’’—including ‘‘any information
service’’—‘‘unfettered by Federal or
State regulation.’’ The Commission has
observed that this provision makes clear
that ‘‘federal authority [is] preeminent
in the area of information services’’ and
that information services ‘‘should
remain free of regulation.’’ To this same
end, by directing that a communications
service provider ‘‘shall be treated as a
common carrier under [this Act] only to
the extent that it is engaged in providing
telecommunications services,’’ Section
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
3(51)—also added by the 1996 Act—
forbids any common-carriage regulation,
whether federal or state, of information
services.
185. Finally, our preemption
authority finds further support in the
Act’s forbearance provision. Under
Section 10(e) of the Act, Commission
forbearance determinations expressly
preempt any contrary state regulatory
efforts. It would be incongruous if state
and local regulation were preempted
when the Commission decides to
forbear from a provision that would
otherwise apply, or if the Commission
adopts a regulation and then forbears
from it, but not preempted when the
Commission determines that a
requirement does not apply in the first
place. Nothing in the Act suggests that
Congress intended for state or local
governments to be able to countermand
a federal policy of nonregulation or to
possess any greater authority over
broadband internet access service than
that exercised by the federal
government. Some commenters note
that Section 253(c), 47 U.S.C. 253(c),
preserves certain state authority over
telecommunications services. But that
provision has no relevance here, given
our finding that broadband internet
access service is an information service.
Although Section 253(c) recognizes that
states have historically played a role in
regulating telecommunications services,
there is no such tradition of state
regulation of information services,
which have long been governed by a
federal policy of nonregulation.
8. Disability Access Provisions
186. The Communications Act
provides the Commission with authority
to ensure that consumers with
disabilities can access broadband
networks regardless of whether
broadband internet access service is
classified as telecommunications service
or information service. The TwentyFirst Century Communications and
Video Accessibility Act of 2010 (CVAA)
already applies a variety of accessibility
requirements to broadband internet
access service. Congress adopted the
CVAA after recognizing that ‘‘internetbased and digital technologies . . .
driven by growth in broadband . . . are
now pervasive, offering innovative and
exciting ways to communicate and share
information.’’ Congress thus clearly had
internet-based communications
technologies in mind when enacting the
accessibility provisions of Section 716
(as well as the related provisions of
Sections 717–718) and in providing
important protections with respect to
advanced communications services
(ACS). ACS means: ‘‘(A) interconnected
PO 00000
Frm 00040
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
VoIP service; (B) non-interconnected
VoIP service; (C) electronic messaging
service; and (D) interoperable video
conferencing service.’’ In particular, to
ensure that people with disabilities have
access to the communications
technologies of the Twenty-First
Century, the CVAA added several
provisions to the Communications Act,
including Section 716 of the Act, which
requires that providers of advanced
communications services (ACS) and
manufacturers of equipment used for
ACS make their services and products
accessible to people with disabilities,
unless it is not achievable to do so.
These mandates already apply
according to their terms in the context
of broadband internet access service.
The CVAA also adopted a requirement,
in Section 718, that ensures access to
internet browsers in wireless phones for
people who are blind and visually
impaired. In addition, the CVAA
directed the Commission to enact
regulations to prescribe, among other
things, that networks used to provide
ACS ‘‘may not impair or impede the
accessibility of information content
when accessibility has been
incorporated into that content for
transmission through . . . networks
used to provide [ACS].’’ Finally, new
Section 717 creates new enforcement
and recordkeeping requirements
applicable to Sections 255, 716, and
718. Section 710 of the Act addressing
hearing aid compatibility and
implementing rules enacted thereunder
also apply regardless of any action taken
in this Order. To the extent that other
accessibility issues arise, we will
address those issues in separate
proceedings in furtherance of our
statutory authority to ensure that
broadband networks are accessible to
and usable by individuals with
disabilities.
9. Continued Applicability of Title III
Licensing Provisions
187. We also note that our decision
today to classify wireless broadband
internet access service as an information
service does not affect the general
applicability of the spectrum allocation
and licensing provisions of Title III and
the Commission’s rules to this service.
Title III generally provides the
Commission with authority to regulate
‘‘radio communications’’ and
‘‘transmission of energy by radio.’’
Among other provisions, Title III gives
the Commission the authority to adopt
rules preventing interference and allows
it to classify radio stations. It also
establishes the basic licensing scheme
for radio stations, allowing the
Commission to grant, revoke, or modify
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
licenses. Title III further allows the
Commission to make such rules and
regulations and prescribe such
restrictions and conditions as may be
necessary to carry out the provisions of
the Act. Provisions governing access to
and use of spectrum (and their
corresponding Commission rules) do
not depend on whether the service
using the spectrum is classified as a
telecommunications or information
service under the Act.
II. A Light–Touch Framework To
Restore Internet Freedom
188. For decades, the lodestar of the
Commission’s approach to preserving
internet freedom was a light-touch,
market-based approach. This approach
debuted at the dawn of the commercial
internet during the Clinton
Administration, when an overwhelming
bipartisan consensus made it national
policy to preserve a digital free market
‘‘unfettered by Federal or State
regulation.’’ It continued during the
Bush Administration, as reflected in the
‘‘Four Freedoms’’ articulated by
Chairman Powell in 2004 and was then
formally adopted by a unanimous
Commission in 2005 as well as in a
series of classification decisions
reviewed above. These include the
freedoms for consumers to (1) ‘‘access
the lawful internet content of their
choice’’; (2) ‘‘run applications and use
services of their choice, subject to the
needs of law enforcement’’; (3) ‘‘connect
their choice of legal devices that do not
harm the network’’; and (4) ‘‘enjoy
competition among network providers,
application and service providers, and
content providers.’’ And it continued for
the first six years of the Obama
Administration. We reaffirm and honor
this longstanding, bipartisan
commitment by adopting a light-touch
framework that will preserve internet
freedom for all Americans.
189. To implement that light-touch
framework, we next reevaluate the rules
and enforcement regime adopted in the
Title II Order. That reevaluation is
informed—as it must be—by the return
of jurisdiction to the Federal Trade
Commission to police ISPs for
anticompetitive acts or unfair and
deceptive practices. Against that
backdrop, we first decide to retain the
transparency rule adopted in the Open
Internet Order with slight modifications.
History has shown that transparency is
critical to openness—consumers and
entrepreneurs are not afraid to make
their voices heard when ISPs engage in
practices to which they object. And we
conclude that preexisting federal
protections—alongside the transparency
rule we adopt today—are not only
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
sufficient to protect internet freedom,
but will do so more effectively and at
lower social cost than the Title II
Order’s conduct rules. In short, we
believe the light-touch framework we
adopt today will pave the way for
additional innovation and investment
that will facilitate greater consumer
access to more content, services, and
devices, and greater competition.
A. Transparency
190. ‘‘Sunlight,’’ Justice Brandeis
famously noted, ‘‘is . . . the best of
disinfectants.’’ This is the case in our
domain. Properly tailored transparency
disclosures provide valuable
information to the Commission to
enable it to meet its statutory obligation
to observe the communications
marketplace to monitor the introduction
of new services and technologies, and to
identify and eliminate potential
marketplace barriers for the provision of
information services. Such disclosures
also provide valuable information to
other internet ecosystem participants;
transparency substantially reduces the
possibility that ISPs will engage in
harmful practices, and it incentivizes
quick corrective measures by providers
if problematic conduct is identified.
Appropriate disclosures help consumers
make informed choices about their
purchase and use of broadband internet
access services. Moreover, clear
disclosures improve consumer
confidence in ISPs’ practices while
providing entrepreneurs and other small
businesses the information they may
need to innovate and improve products.
191. Today, we commit to balanced
ISP transparency requirements based on
a sound legal footing. We return, with
minor adjustments, to the transparency
rule adopted in the 2010 Open Internet
Order, which provides consumers and
the Commission with essential
information while minimizing the
burdens imposed on ISPs. In so doing,
we modify the existing transparency
rule to eliminate many of the
burdensome additional reporting
obligations adopted by the Commission
in the Title II Order. We find that those
additional obligations do not benefit
consumers, entrepreneurs, or the
Commission sufficiently to outweigh the
burdens imposed on ISPs. The
transparency rule we adopt will aid the
Commission in ‘‘identifying . . . market
entry barriers for entrepreneurs and
other small businesses in the provision
and ownership of . . . information
services.’’ We also conclude that our
transparency rule readily survives First
Amendment scrutiny. The disclosure
requirements we adopt apply to both
fixed and mobile ISPs.
PO 00000
Frm 00041
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
7891
1. History of the Transparency Rule
192. The Open Internet Order. The
transparency rule, first adopted in the
Open Internet Order, requires both fixed
and mobile ISPs to ‘‘publicly disclose
accurate information regarding the
network management practices,
performance, and commercial terms of
its broadband internet access services
sufficient for consumers to make
informed choices.’’ In addition, the
Open Internet Order provided guidance
on both what information should be
disclosed and how those disclosures
should be made. The Commission
described the types of information that
should be included in each category, but
emphasized the importance of flexibility
in implementing the rule, making clear
that ‘‘effective disclosures will likely
include some or all’’ of the listed types
of information. Though the other rules
adopted in the Open Internet Order
were overturned, the D.C. Circuit
upheld the transparency rule in
Verizon.
193. 2011 Advisory Guidance. On
June 30, 2011, the Enforcement Bureau
and Office of General Counsel released
guidance ‘‘regarding specific methods of
disclosure that will be considered to
comply with the transparency rule,’’
addressing concerns about the scope of
required disclosures and potential
burdens on small providers. The 2011
Advisory Guidance provided detail on
methods for disclosure of actual
performance metrics, and the contents
of the disclosures regarding network
practices, performance characteristics,
and commercial terms, and clarified the
requirement that disclosures be made
‘‘at the point of sale.’’ The 2011
Advisory Guidance clarified that
disclosure of the information listed in
paragraphs 56 and 98 of the Open
Internet Order was sufficient to satisfy
the transparency rule notwithstanding
the Open Internet Order’s assertion that
the list was ‘‘not necessarily exhaustive,
nor is it a safe harbor.’’ Paragraph 56 of
the Open Internet Order provided the
following non-exhaustive list of
disclosures: network practices,
including congestion management,
application-specific behavior, device
attachment rules, and security;
performance characteristics, including a
service description and the impact of
specialized services; and commercial
terms, including pricing, privacy
policies, and redress options. Paragraph
98 made clear that mobile ISPs must
comply with the transparency
requirements and states that such
providers must ‘‘disclose their thirdparty device and application
certification procedures, if any’’;
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
7892
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
‘‘clearly explain their criteria for any
restrictions on use of their network’’;
and ‘‘expeditiously inform device and
application providers of any decisions
to deny access to the network or of a
failure to approve their particular
devices or applications.’’
194. 2014 Advisory Guidance. In July
2014, in the wake of the Verizon
decision, the Enforcement Bureau
issued further guidance emphasizing the
importance of consistency between an
ISP’s disclosures under the transparency
rule and that provider’s advertising
claims or other public statements. The
2014 Advisory Guidance explained that
the transparency rule ‘‘prevents a
broadband internet access provider from
making assertions about its service that
contain errors, are inconsistent with the
provider’s disclosure statement, or are
misleading or deceptive.’’
195. Title II Order. In the Title II
Order, the Commission broadened the
transparency rule’s requirements by
interpreting the rule to mandate certain
additional reporting obligations it
termed ‘‘enhancements.’’ These
additional reporting obligations,
although falling within the same broad
categories as those listed in the Open
Internet Order, required that providers
include far greater technical detail in
their disclosures. For example, all ISPs,
except small providers exempt under
the Small Provider Waiver Order, were
required to make specific disclosures
regarding the commercial terms
(including specific information
regarding prices and fees), performance
characteristics (including, for example,
packet loss and a requirement that these
disclosures be reasonably related to the
performance a consumer could expect
in the geographic area in which they are
purchasing service), and network
practices (including, for example,
application and user-based practices) of
the broadband internet access services
they offer. The Open Internet Order,
read together with the 2011 Advisory
Guidance, limited the performance
characteristic disclosures to a service
description (‘‘[a] general description of
the service, including the service
technology, expected and actual access
speed and latency, and the suitability of
the service for real-time applications’’)
and the impact of specialized services.
The Open Internet Order included
specific disclosures related to
congestion management, applicationspecific behavior, device attachment
rules, and security. The Title II Order
also established a safe harbor for the
form and format of disclosures intended
for consumers and delegated
development of the format to the
agency’s Consumer Advisory Committee
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
(CAC). The 2016 Advisory Guidance,
released on delegated authority,
provided examples of acceptable
methodologies for disclosure of
performance characteristics and offered
guidance regarding compliance with the
point of sale requirement. For example,
the guidance notes that for many fixed
providers, performance is likely to be
consistent across the provider’s
footprint so long as the same technology
is deployed and that in such a case a
single disclosure for the full service area
may be sufficient. By contrast, mobile
performance may vary, and the
guidance suggested the use of CMA as
an appropriate geographic area on
which to base disclosures.
2. Refining the Transparency Rule
196. Today, we retain the
transparency rule as established in the
Open Internet Order, with some
modifications, and eliminate the
additional reporting obligations of the
Title II Order. We find many of those
additional reporting obligations
significantly increased the burdens
imposed on ISPs without providing
countervailing benefits to consumers or
the Commission. As a result, we
recalibrate the requirements under the
transparency rule. Specifically, we
adopt the following rule:
Any person providing broadband
internet access service shall publicly
disclose accurate information regarding
the network management practices,
performance, and commercial terms of
its broadband internet access services
sufficient to enable consumers to make
informed choices regarding the
purchase and use of such services and
entrepreneurs and other small
businesses to develop, market, and
maintain internet offerings. Such
disclosure shall be made via a publicly
available, easily accessible website or
through transmittal to the Commission.
For purposes of these rules,
‘‘consumer’’ includes any subscriber to
the ISP’s broadband internet access
service, and ‘‘person’’ includes any
‘‘individual, group of individuals,
corporation, partnership, association,
unit of government or legal entity,
however organized.’’
197. In doing so, we note that the
record overwhelmingly supports
retaining at least some transparency
requirements. Crucially, the
transparency rule will ensure that
consumers have the information
necessary to make informed choices
about the purchase and use of
broadband internet access service,
which promotes a competitive
marketplace for those services.
Disclosure supports innovation,
PO 00000
Frm 00042
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
investment, and competition by
ensuring that entrepreneurs and other
small businesses have the technical
information necessary to create and
maintain online content, applications,
services, and devices, and to assess the
risks and benefits of embarking on new
projects. We reject commenter
assertions that we should not maintain
any transparency requirements.
CenturyLink does not identify which
requirements from the 2010
transparency rule it believes could
arguably be ‘‘onerous.’’ Further, as
discussed above, we find that a
transparency requirement is necessary
and sufficient to protect internet
openness, given that we lack authority
to adopt conduct rules and in addition
find that an enforceable transparency
rule obviates the need for bright line
conduct rules.
198. What is more, disclosure
increases the likelihood that ISPs will
abide by open internet principles by
reducing the incentives and ability to
violate those principles, that the
internet community will identify
problematic conduct, and that those
affected by such conduct will be in a
position to make informed competitive
choices or seek available remedies for
anticompetitive, unfair, or deceptive
practices. Transparency thereby
‘‘increases the likelihood that harmful
practices will not occur in the first place
and that, if they do, they will be quickly
remedied.’’ We apply our transparency
rule to broadband internet access
service, as well as functional
equivalents or any service that is used
to evade the transparency requirements
we adopt today. As the Commission
explained in the Open Internet Order,
‘‘a key factor in determining whether a
service is used to evade the scope of the
rules is whether the service is used as
a substitute for broadband internet
access service. For example, an internet
access service that provides access to a
substantial subset of internet endpoints
based on end users’ preference to avoid
certain content, applications, or
services; internet access services that
allow some uses of the internet (such as
access to the World Wide Web) but not
others (such as email); or a ‘Best of the
Web’ internet access service that
provides access to 100 top websites
could not be used to evade the open
internet rules applicable to ‘broadband
internet access service.’ ’’ We caution
ISPs that they may not evade
application of the transparency rule
‘‘simply by blocking end users’ access to
some internet points.’’
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
a. Content of Required Disclosures
199. We require ISPs to prominently
disclose network management practices,
performance, and commercial terms of
their broadband internet access service,
and find substantial record support
(including from ISPs) for following the
course set out by the Open Internet
Order. We find that the elements of the
transparency rule we adopt today help
consumers make the most educated
decision as to which ISP to choose and
keep entrepreneurs and other small
businesses effectively informed of ISP
practices so that they can develop,
market, and maintain internet offerings.
Although we agree with the Open
Internet Order that ‘‘the best approach is
to allow flexibility in implementation of
the transparency rule,’’ we describe the
specific requirements to guide ISPs and
ensure that consumers, entrepreneurs,
and other small businesses receive
sufficient information to make our rule
effective.
200. Network Management Practices.
In the Open Internet Order, the
Commission required ISPs to disclose
their congestion management,
application-specific behavior, device
attachment rules, and security practices.
We adopt those same requirements and
further require ISPs to disclose any
blocking, throttling, affiliated
prioritization, or paid prioritization in
which they engage. Although requiring
disclosure of network management
practices imposes some burden on ISPs,
we find the benefits of enabling the
public and the Commission to identify
any problematic conduct and suggest
fixes substantially outweigh those costs.
The record generally supports
disclosure of ISP network practices.
201. We specifically require all ISPs
to disclose:
• Blocking. Any practice (other than
reasonable network management
elsewhere disclosed) that blocks or
otherwise prevents end user access to
lawful content, applications, service, or
non-harmful devices, including a
description of what is blocked.
• Throttling. Any practice (other than
reasonable network management
elsewhere disclosed) that degrades or
impairs access to lawful internet traffic
on the basis of content, application,
service, user, or use of a non-harmful
device, including a description of what
is throttled.
• Affiliated Prioritization. Any
practice that directly or indirectly favors
some traffic over other traffic, including
through use of techniques such as traffic
shaping, prioritization, or resource
reservation, to benefit an affiliate,
including identification of the affiliate.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
• Paid Prioritization. Any practice
that directly or indirectly favors some
traffic over other traffic, including
through use of techniques such as traffic
shaping, prioritization, or resource
reservation, in exchange for
consideration, monetary or otherwise.
• Congestion Management.
Descriptions of congestion management
practices, if any. These descriptions
should include the types of traffic
subject to the practices; the purposes
served by the practices; the practices’
effects on end users’ experience; criteria
used in practices, such as indicators of
congestion that trigger a practice,
including any usage limits triggering the
practice, and the typical frequency of
congestion; usage limits and the
consequences of exceeding them; and
references to engineering standards,
where appropriate.
• Application-Specific Behavior.
Whether and why the ISP blocks or ratecontrols specific protocols or protocol
ports, modifies protocol fields in ways
not prescribed by the protocol standard,
or otherwise inhibits or favors certain
applications or classes of applications.
• Device Attachment Rules. Any
restrictions on the types of devices and
any approval procedures for devices to
connect to the network.
• Security. Any practices used to
ensure end-user security or security of
the network, including types of
triggering conditions that cause a
mechanism to be invoked (but
excluding information that could
reasonably be used to circumvent
network security). We expect ISPs to
exercise their judgment in deciding
whether it is necessary and appropriate
to disclose particular security measures.
The Commission’s primary concern is
those security measures likely to affect
a consumer’s ability to access the
content, applications, services, and
devices of his or her choice. As a result,
we do not expect ISPs to disclose
internal network security measures that
do not directly bear on a consumer’s
choices.
We do not mandate disclosure of any
other network management practices.
Notably, we define ‘‘reasonable network
management’’ to mean a practice
‘‘appropriate and tailored to achieving a
legitimate network management
purpose, taking into account the
particular network architecture and
technology of the broadband internet
access service.’’ The record reflects an
overwhelming preference for this
approach from the Open Internet Order,
which provides ISPs greater flexibility
and certainty.
202. Performance Characteristics. In
the Open Internet Order, the
PO 00000
Frm 00043
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
7893
Commission required ISPs to disclose a
service description as well as the impact
of specialized services (non-broadband
internet access service data services) on
performance. We find that the Open
Internet Order’s performance metric
disclosures benefit consumers without
placing an undue burden on ISPs.
203. We specifically require all ISPs
to disclose:
• Service Description. A general
description of the service, including the
service technology, expected and actual
access speed and latency, and the
suitability of the service for real-time
applications. For purposes of satisfying
this requirement, fixed ISPs that choose
to participate in the Measuring
Broadband America (MBA) program
may disclose their results as a sufficient
representation of the actual performance
their customers can expect to
experience. Fixed ISPs that do not
participate may use the methodology
from the MBA program to measure
actual performance, or may disclose
actual performance based on internal
testing, consumer speed test data, or
other data regarding network
performance, including reliable,
relevant data from third-party sources.
Mobile ISPs that have access to reliable
information on network performance
may disclose the results of their own or
third-party testing. Those mobile ISPs
that do not have reasonable access to
such network performance data may
disclose a Typical Speed Range (TSR)
representing the range of speeds and
latency that can be expected by most of
their customers, for each technology/
service tier offered, along with a
statement that such information is the
best approximation available to the
broadband provider of the actual speeds
and latency experienced by its
subscribers.
• Impact of Non-Broadband Internet
Access Service Data Services. If
applicable, what non-broadband
internet access service data services, if
any, are offered to end users, and
whether and how any non-broadband
internet access service data services may
affect the last-mile capacity available
for, and the performance of, broadband
internet access service.
204. Commercial Terms. In the Open
Internet Order, the Commission
required ISPs to disclose commercial
terms of service, including price,
privacy policies, and redress options.
The record in this proceeding supports
retaining these disclosures. These
disclosures inform the Commission,
consumers, entrepreneurs, and other
small businesses about the parameters
of the service, without imposing costly
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
7894
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
burdens on ISPs. We therefore require
ISPs to make the following disclosures:
• Price. For example, monthly prices,
usage-based fees, and fees for early
termination or additional network
services.
• Privacy Policies. A complete and
accurate disclosure about the ISP’s
privacy practices, if any. For example,
whether any network management
practices entail inspection of network
traffic, and whether traffic is stored,
provided to third parties, or used by the
ISP for non-network management
purposes.
• Redress Options. Practices for
resolving complaints and questions
from consumers, entrepreneurs, and
other small businesses.
205. Eliminating the Title II Order’s
Additional Reporting Obligations.
Today, we return to a more balanced
approach—one that provides sufficient
information for the Commission to meet
its statutory requirements, enables
consumers to make informed choices
about the purchase and use of
broadband internet access service, and
ensures entrepreneurs and other small
businesses can develop, market, and
maintain internet offerings, while
minimizing costly and unnecessary
burdens on ISPs.
206. We eliminate the additional
reporting obligations adopted in the
Title II Order and the related guidance
in the 2016 Advisory Guidance and
return to the requirements established
in the Open Internet Order. We find that
these additional reporting obligations
unduly burden ISPs without providing
a comparable benefit to consumers. That
is especially true for the performance
metric, which mandated disclosure of
packet loss, geographically-specific
disclosures, and disclosure of
performance at peak usage times among
other things.
207. The record supports the
elimination of these additional reporting
obligations and our return to the
requirements under the Open Internet
Order. The record indicates that the
additional performance disclosures are
among the most burdensome.
CenturyLink estimated that during the
two-year period from February 2015
through February 2017, 1,650 hours of
employee time were required to comply
with the additional reporting
obligations, compared to 860 additional
hours spent complying with the other
new requirements of the Title II Order.
Disclosure of packet loss, for example,
requires providers to conduct additional
engineering analysis. Notably, the Office
of Management and Budget (OMB) in
the prior Administration declined to
approve packet loss when reviewing
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
these additional reporting obligations
for mobile ISPs, suggesting concern that
the additional reporting obligations
provided little consumer benefit relative
to their cost. After all, consumers have
little understanding of what packet loss
means; what they do want to know is
whether their internet access service
will support real-time applications,
which is the consumer-facing impact of
these performance metrics. Although
some commenters argue that additional
reporting of these esoteric metrics are
valuable to some consumers and
entrepreneurs, they provide inadequate
support for these benefits. In addition,
providing such information imposes
significant costs on providers. Weighing
the additional costs to ISPs against the
limited incremental benefits to
consumers, entrepreneurs, and small
businesses, we conclude that the net
benefits of these additional reporting
obligations are likely negative. The
approach we take today achieves the
benefits of transparency at much lower
cost than the Title II Order.
208. Small Providers. Small providers
have asked us to maintain the
exemption found in the Small Provider
Order to the extent that any of
additional reporting obligations still
apply. Because the requirements we
adopt today eliminate all of these
additional obligations and do not
impose disparately high burdens on
small providers, we find an exemption
for small providers unnecessary.
Further, the requirements are critical to
ensuring that consumers have sufficient
information to make informed choices
in their selection of ISPs and to deter
ISPs from secretly erecting barriers to
market entry by entrepreneurs and other
small businesses. As a result, we decline
to provide an exemption for smaller
providers at this time.
b. Means and Format of Disclosure
209. Means of Disclosure. The
Commission relies on ISP disclosures to
identify market-entry barriers for
entrepreneurs and small businesses and
ensure consumers have the information
they need in selecting an ISP. And given
the sheer number of ISPs offering
service throughout the country—4,559
at last count—we believe the most
effective way to monitor for any such
barriers is to require the public
disclosure of an ISP’s practices so that
Commission staff can review them
while letting consumers, entrepreneurs,
and other small businesses report to the
Commission any market-barriers they
discover. Accordingly, ISPs must
publicly disclose the information
required by our transparency rule.
PO 00000
Frm 00044
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
210. We give ISPs two options for
disclosure. First, they may include the
disclosures on a publicly available,
easily accessible website. Consistent
with Commission precedent, we expect
that ISPs will make disclosures in a
manner accessible by people with
disabilities. ISPs doing so need not
distribute hard copy versions of the
required disclosures and need not file
them with the Commission, which can
review the disclosures as needed on the
ISPs’ websites. For ISPs electing this
option, we reaffirm the means of
disclosure requirement from the Open
Internet Order and the clarification
found in the 2011 Advisory Guidance.
Alternatively, ISPs may transmit their
disclosures to the Commission, and we
will make them available on a publicly
available, easily accessible website. We
direct the Consumer and Governmental
Affairs Bureau, in coordination with the
Wireline Competition Bureau, to issue a
Public Notice explaining how ISPs can
exercise this option. We also note that
ISPs that do not transmit their
disclosures to the FCC will be deemed
as having elected the first option (and
may later elect that option despite prior
transmittal by informing the
Commission in a manner specified in
the aforementioned Public Notice). By
offering these two options, we allow
ISPs (and especially smaller ISPs) the
ability to choose the least burdensome
method of disclosure that will
nonetheless ensure that Commission
staff, consumers, entrepreneurs, and
other small businesses have access to
the information they need in carrying
out our obligation to identify marketentry barriers.
211. We also eliminate the direct
notification requirement adopted in the
Title II Order. We find the direct
notification requirement unduly
burdensome to ISPs and unnecessary in
light of the other forms of public
disclosure required. In contrast, we find
that the disclosures adopted in the Open
Internet Order and 2011 Advisory
Guidance appropriately balance making
information easy to reach and the costs
of disclosure for ISPs.
212. Format of Disclosure. We
eliminate the consumer broadband label
safe harbor for form and format of
disclosures adopted in the Title II Order.
Adopting the label could require some
ISPs to expend substantial resources to
tailor their disclosures to fit the format.
And limited adoption, caused by the
potentially high burdens associated
with adapting disclosures to a particular
format, significantly reduces the value
of the uniform format. Moreover,
mandating such a format would increase
the burden for those ISPs required to
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
revise their existing disclosure to
conform to the mandated format. We
find that requiring all ISPs to disclose
the same information, regardless of
format, will allow for comparability
between offerings, and enable the
Commission to meet its statutory
reporting requirements.
3. Authority for the Transparency Rule
213. Just as the Commission did in the
Open Internet Order, we rely on Section
257 of the Communications Act as
authority for the transparency
requirements we retain. Section 257(a)
directs the Commission to ‘‘identify[ ]
and eliminat[e] . . . market entry
barriers for entrepreneurs and other
small businesses in the provision and
ownership of telecommunications
services and information services, or in
the provision of parts or services to
providers of telecommunications
services and information services.’’
Section 257(a) set a deadline of 15
months from the enactment of the 1996
Act for the Commission’s initial effort in
that regard, and Section 257(c) directs
the Commission, triennially thereafter,
to report to Congress on such
marketplace barriers and how they have
been addressed by regulation or could
be addressed by recommended statutory
changes. Consistent with the
Commission’s longstanding view,
Section 257(c) is properly understood as
imposing a continuing obligation on the
agency to identify barriers described in
Section 257(a) that may emerge in the
future, rather than limited to those
identified in the original Section 257(a)
proceeding. Because Sections 257(a) and
(c) clearly anticipate that the
Commission and Congress would take
steps to help eliminate previouslyidentified marketplace barriers, limiting
the triennial reports only to those
barriers identified in the original
Section 257(a) proceeding could make
such reports of little to no ongoing value
over time. We thus find it far more
reasonable to interpret Section 257(c) as
contemplating that the Commission will
perform an ongoing market review to
identify any new barriers to entry, and
that the statutory duty to ‘‘identify and
eliminate’’ implicitly empowers the
Commission to require disclosures from
those third parties who possess the
information necessary for the
Commission and Congress to find and
remedy market entry barriers. Although
Section 257 does not specify precisely
how the Commission should obtain and
analyze information for purposes of its
reports to Congress, we construe the
statutory mandate to ‘‘identify’’ the
presence of market barriers as including
within it direct authority to collect
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
evidence to prove that such barriers
exist. While this direct authority
suffices to support the Commission’s
adoption of the transparency rule,
Sections 4, 201(b), and 303(r) of the Act
also give us rulemaking authority to
implement the Act, including the
provisions we rely on as authority for
our transparency requirements. In his
partial concurrence and partial dissent
in Verizon, Judge Silberman stated with
respect to the transparency rule that
‘‘[t]he Commission is required to make
triennial reports to Congress on ‘market
entry barriers’ in information service,
and requiring disclosure of network
management practices appears to be
reasonably ancillary to that duty.’’
214. Our disclosure requirements will
help us both identify and address
potential market entry barriers in the
provision and ownership of information
services and the provision of parts and
services to information service
providers. In particular, some internet
applications and services previously
have been found to be information
services, and, more generally,
entrepreneurs and small businesses
participating in the internet marketplace
could be seeking to act as either
providers of information services or
providers of parts and services to
information services (or both). The
language of Section 257(a) appears
reasonably read to encompass those
entrepreneurs’ and small businesses’
services under one or more of the
covered categories, and there is no
dispute in the record in that regard.
Because we find that internet
entrepreneurs and small businesses that
depend on their customers using
broadband internet access service are
covered by Section 257(a) in any case,
we need not and do not address with
greater specificity the specific category
or categories into which particular edge
services fall. In addition, the manner in
which an ISP provides broadband
internet access service, including but
not limited to its network management
practices, can affect how well particular
internet applications or services of
entrepreneurs and small businesses
perform when used by that ISP’s
subscribers. Aspects of the performance
of broadband internet access services,
particularly if undisclosed, thus could
constitute barriers within the scope of
Section 257(a) in the future, depending
on how the marketplace evolves,
regardless of whether or not particular
practices do so today. For example, if
ISPs do not disclose key details of how
they provide broadband internet access
service, that could leave entrepreneurs
and small businesses participating in
PO 00000
Frm 00045
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
7895
the internet marketplace unable to
determine how well particular existing
or contemplated offerings are likely to
perform for users, and thus unable to
determine if their service will be usable
to a sufficient number of potential
customers to make the offering viable.
Such undisclosed practices also can
leave consumers unable to judge which
broadband internet access service
offerings will best meet their needs
given the applications and service they
wish to use. As a result, even if a
sufficient number of consumers
theoretically are accessible by a
broadband internet access service
offering with sufficient technical
characteristics to make a given internet
application or service viable, an
entrepreneur’s or small business’s entry
into the market for that service could be
undermined if consumers are unable to
identify which of the various broadband
internet access services offerings has the
required technical characteristics. By
contrast, the record reveals that the
disclosure of practices and service
characteristics we require today helps
entrepreneurs and small businesses
understand how well particular internet
application or service offerings are
likely to work with particular ISPs’
broadband internet access services and
helps consumers make the most
educated choice among ISPs and
particular broadband internet access
service offerings, especially if they have
particular interests in using internet
applications or services that are highly
dependent on broadband internet access
service performance. The disclosures
themselves thus are likely to reduce any
potential risk of particular practices
being such a barrier—had they not been
publicly disclosed—and also enable us
to recommend to Congress any
legislative changes that we might find
warranted based on our analysis of these
practices. While we observe that the
transparency rule will help eliminate
potential barriers, our reliance on
Section 257 as authority for the
transparency rule centers on the need
for that rule to identify barriers and
report to Congress in that regard.
Contrary to some arguments, we thus do
not interpret Section 257 as an overarching grant of authority to eliminate
any and all barriers we might identify.
We also are not persuaded by summary
claims that Section 257 does not grant
us authority here insofar as those claims
lack meaningful analysis of the text of
that provision. Thus, we continue to
believe that Section 257 provides us
authority for the rule we adopt.
215. We believe that eliminating
market entry barriers in the provision
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
7896
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
and ownership of information services
and the provision of parts and services
to information service providers will
help bring the benefits of new
inventions and developments to the
public. In addition, we conclude that
the oversight over ISPs’ practices that
the Commission, FTC, and other
antitrust and consumer protection
authorities can exercise as a result of the
transparency rule likewise will promote
innovation and competition, spreading
the benefits of technological
development to the American people
broadly.
216. The Transparency Requirements
Are Consistent With the First
Amendment. We conclude that the
transparency requirements represent
permissible regulation of commercial
speech. The ultimate effect of the
required disclosures is to ensure that
key details regarding service
characteristics, rates, and terms of
broadband internet access service
offerings are available to potential
customers before they make their
purchasing decisions. As stated above,
ISPs have two options for complying
with the transparency requirements.
One is to make the disclosures on a
publicly available, easily accessible
website. Alternatively, ISPs can elect to
simply provide that information to the
Commission, which will then itself
make the information publicly available.
The Title II Order evaluated the
transparency rule at issue there under
Zauderer v. Office of Disciplinary
Counsel of Supreme Court of Ohio, and
there is some record support for
applying that framework. We recognize
that there remains some debate
regarding the application of Zauderer,
as opposed to the Central Hudson
framework that generally governs First
Amendment review of commercial
speech regulation. We need not resolve
that here, because we find that our rule
would withstand scrutiny even under
Central Hudson. In particular, our
transparency rule directly advances
substantial government interests and is
no more extensive than necessary.
217. The transparency requirements
we retain directly advance substantial
government interests in encouraging
competition and innovation. The Act
itself reveals the significance of these
interests. In Section 257 of the Act,
Congress specifically directed the
Commission to identify market entry
barriers in the provision of information
services and their inputs, eliminating
them where possible, and reporting to
Congress on the need for any statutory
changes required to address such
barriers. In carrying out our
responsibilities under Section 257,
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
Congress directed us to advance, among
other things, ‘‘vigorous economic
competition’’ and ‘‘technological
advancement.’’ Such interests are
similar to those recognized as
substantial by courts, as well.
218. The disclosure of information
regarding broadband internet access
service characteristics, rates, and terms
directly advance those statutory
directives. We thus disagree with
arguments that there is insufficient
justification for our transparency
requirements to withstand First
Amendment scrutiny. Moreover,
commenters do not cite precedent
demonstrating that only ‘‘systematic or
enduring problem[s]’’ can provide the
basis for requirements that withstand
First Amendment scrutiny. Broadband
internet access service subscribers will
be able to use the disclosed information
to evaluate broadband internet access
service offerings and determine which
offering will best enable the use of the
applications and service they desire.
This helps guard against the potential
barrier to entry and deterrent to
technological advancement that
otherwise could be faced by
entrepreneurs’ and small business’
innovative internet applications and
service offerings, which may be
dependent on the technical
characteristics of broadband internet
access service. The information
disclosed by ISPs also is relevant to
internet application and service
providers’ purchase of services from
those ISPs. The record reveals evidence
that a number of the internet
applications and services that might be
particularly sensitive to the manner in
which an ISP provides broadband
internet access service potentially could
benefit from the freedom this order
provides for providers of such services
and ISPs to enter prioritization
arrangements to better ensure the
performance of those internet
applications and services. Thus, the
disclosures enable entrepreneurs, small
businesses, and other participants in the
internet marketplace to evaluate how
well their offerings will perform by
default relative to the prioritization
services that ISPs offer them. Enabling
internet application and service
providers to evaluate their options in
this way helps reduce barriers to entry
that otherwise could exist and
encourages entrepreneurs’ and small
businesses’ ability to compete and
develop and advance innovating
offerings in furtherance of our statutory
objectives. In addition to those
considerations, as the Commission has
recognized, disclosures help ensure
PO 00000
Frm 00046
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
accountability by ISPs and the potential
for quick remedies if problematic
practices occur. The disclosures also
provide the Commission the
information it needs for the evaluation
required by Section 257 of the Act,
enabling us to spur regulatory action or
seek legislative changes as needed. The
transparency rule we retain thus
directly advances the substantial
government interests identified in
Section 257 of the Act.
219. The transparency requirements
also are no more extensive than
necessary. The disclosures covered by
our transparency rule are tied to our
duties under Section 257 of the
Communications Act. We also observe
in this regard that the most significant
concerns were raised with respect to the
additional reporting obligations adopted
in the Title II Order and here we
eliminate those requirements in favor of
a rule consistent in scope with the 2010
transparency rule. In addition, an ISP’s
direct public disclosure of the
information encompassed by the
transparency rule is just one option; it
may instead submit the information to
the Commission, which would then
make public. We thus conclude that the
transparency requirements are
appropriately tailored to the
Congressionally-recognized goals that
we seek to advance.
B. Bright-Line and General Conduct
Rules
220. We eliminate the conduct rules
adopted in the Title II Order—including
the general conduct rule and the
prohibitions on paid prioritization,
blocking, and throttling. We do so for
three reasons. First, the transparency
rule we adopt, in combination with the
state of broadband internet access
service competition and the antitrust
and consumer protection laws, obviates
the need for conduct rules by achieving
comparable benefits at lower cost.
Second, scrutinizing closely each prior
conduct rule, we find that the costs of
each rule outweigh its benefits. Third,
the record does not identify any legal
authority to adopt conduct rules for all
ISPs, and we decline to distort the
market with a patchwork of nonuniform, limited-purpose rules.
1. Transparency Leads to Openness
221. Transparency, competition,
antitrust laws, and consumer protection
laws achieve similar benefits as conduct
rules at lower cost. The effect of the
transparency rule we adopt is that ISP
practices that involve blocking,
throttling, and other behavior that may
give rise to openness concerns will be
disclosed to the Commission and the
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
public. As the Commission found in the
Open Internet Order, ‘‘disclosure
increases the likelihood that broadband
providers will abide by open internet
principles, and that the internet
community will identify problematic
conduct and suggest fixes . . . thereby
increas[ing] the chances that harmful
practices will not occur in the first place
and that, if they do, they will be quickly
remedied.’’ The transparency rule will
also assist ‘‘third-party experts such as
independent engineers and consumer
watchdogs to monitor and evaluate
network management practices.’’
222. History demonstrates that public
attention, not heavy-handed
Commission regulation, has been most
effective in deterring ISP threats to
openness and bringing about resolution
of the rare incidents that arise. The
Commission has had transparency
requirements in place since 2010, and
there have been very few incidents in
the United States since then that
plausibly raise openness concerns. It is
telling that the two most-discussed
incidents that purportedly demonstrate
the need for conduct rules, concerning
Madison River and Comcast/BitTorrent,
occurred before the Commission had in
place an enforceable transparency rule.
And it was the disclosure, through
complaints to the Commission and
media reports of the conduct at issue in
those incidents, that led to action
against the challenged conduct.
223. As public access to information
on ISP practices has increased, there has
been a shift toward ISPs resolving
openness issues themselves with less
and less need for Commission
intervention. In 2005, the Enforcement
Bureau entered into a consent decree to
resolve the allegations against Madison
River. In 2008, Comcast reached a
settlement with BitTorrent months
before the Commission issued ComcastBitTorrent. By 2012, with a transparency
rule in place, AT&T reversed its
blocking of access to FaceTime over its
cellular network on certain data plans of
its own accord within approximately
three months. This trend toward swift
ISP self-resolution comes, admittedly,
from only a few data points because,
with transparency in place, almost no
incidents of harm to internet openness
have arisen, suggesting that ISPs are
‘‘resolving’’ issues by not letting them
occur in the first place.
224. We think the disinfectant of
public scrutiny and market pressure, not
the threat of heavy-handed Commission
regulation, best explain the paucity of
issues and their increasingly fast ISPdriven resolution. Since the
Commission adopted a transparency
rule in the Open Internet Order, conduct
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
requirements have varied substantially,
from the rules adopted in the Open
Internet Order, to no conduct rules after
the Verizon court case, to the rules
adopted in the Title II Order. Yet
through all that time, the Commission
released only one Notice of Apparent
Liability, against AT&T for allegedly
violating the transparency rule. The
dearth of actions enforcing conduct
rules is striking. Further, the Title II
Order and Open Internet Order do not,
and could not, claim an epidemic or
even uptick of blocking or degradation
of traffic in the wake of the Comcast or
Verizon court decisions vacating the
Commission’s prior attempts at
openness regulation. These time periods
provide a natural experiment disproving
the notion that conduct rules are
necessary to promote openness. We thus
reject arguments to the contrary.
225. Although we think transparency
promotes openness and empowers
consumers, we recognize that regulation
has an important role to play as a
backstop where genuine harm is
possible. In particular, transparency
amplifies the power of antitrust law and
the FTC Act to deter and where needed
remedy behavior that harms consumers.
While some commenters assert that
proof is difficult in antitrust
proceedings, our transparency rule
requires ISPs to outline their business
practices and service offerings
forthrightly and honestly. This
requirement both deters ISPs from
engaging in anticompetitive, unfair, or
deceptive conduct and gives consumers
and regulators the tools they need to
take action in the face of such behavior.
Many ISPs have committed to abide by
open internet principles. By restoring
authority to the FTC to take action
against deceptive ISP conduct,
reclassification empowers the expert
consumer protection agency to exercise
the authority granted to them by
Congress if ISPs fail to live up to their
word and thereby harm consumers.
226. Transparency thus leads to
openness and achieves comparable
benefits to conduct rules. Moreover, the
costs of compliance with a transparency
rule are much lower than the costs of
compliance with conduct rules. We
therefore decline to impose this
additional cost given our view that
transparency drives a free and open
internet, and in light of the FTC’s and
DOJ’s authority to address any potential
harms. To the extent that conduct rules
lead to any additional marginal
deterrence, we deem the substantial
costs—including costs to consumers in
terms of lost innovation as well as
monetary costs to ISPs—not worth the
possible benefits.
PO 00000
Frm 00047
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
7897
2. Costs of Conduct Rules Outweigh
Benefits
a. General Conduct Rule
227. We find that the vague Internet
Conduct Standard is not in the public
interest. Following adoption of this
Order, the FTC will be able to
vigorously protect consumers and
competition through its consumer
protection and antitrust authorities.
Given this, we see little incremental
benefit and significant cost to retaining
the Internet Conduct Standard. The rule
has created uncertainty and likely
denied or delayed consumer access to
innovative new services, and we believe
the net benefit of the Internet Conduct
Standard is negative. As such, we find
commenters urging the Commission to
retain this standard, even with
modifications, unpersuasive.
228. Based on our experience with the
rule and the extensive record, we are
persuaded that the Internet Conduct
Standard is vague and has created
regulatory uncertainty in the
marketplace hindering investment and
innovation. Because the Internet
Conduct Standard is vague, the standard
and its implementing factors do not
provide carriers with adequate notice of
what they are and are not permitted to
do, i.e., the standard does not afford
parties a ‘‘good process for determining
what conduct has actually been
forbidden.’’ The rule simply warns
carriers to behave in accordance with
what the Commission might require,
without articulating any actual
standard. Even ISP practices based on
consumer choice are not presumptively
permitted; they are merely ‘‘less likely’’
to violate the rule. Moreover, the
uncertainty caused by the Internet
Conduct Standard goes far beyond what
supporters characterize as the flexibility
that is necessary in a regulatory
structure to address future harmful
behavior. We thus find that the vague
Internet Conduct Standard subjects
providers to substantial regulatory
uncertainty and that the record before
us demonstrates that the Commission’s
predictive judgment in 2015 that this
uncertainty was ‘‘likely to be short term
and will dissipate over time as the
marketplace internalizes [the] Title II
approach’’ has not been borne out.
229. Increasing our concerns about
the Internet Conduct Standard, other
agencies already have significant
experience protecting against the harms
to competition and to consumers that
the Internet Conduct Standard purports
to reach. The FTC, for example, has
authority over unfair and deceptive
practices, both with respect to
competition and consumer protection.
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
7898
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
We find that the FTC’s authority over
unfair and deceptive practices and
antitrust laws, with guidance from its
ample body of precedent, already
provides the appropriate flexibility and
predictability to protect consumers and
competition and addresses new
practices that might develop with less
harm to innovation. We also observe
that because FTC and antitrust authority
apply across industries, further
precedent is likely to develop more
quickly, while a sector-specific general
conduct rule is likely to develop more
slowly. While antitrust laws use a
consumer welfare standard defined by
economic analysis to evaluate harmful
conduct, the Internet Conduct Standard
includes a non-exhaustive grab bag of
considerations that are much broader
and hazier than the consumer welfare
standard, and leaves the door open for
the Commission to consider other
factors or unspecified conduct it would
like to take into account.
230. We anticipate that eliminating
the vague Internet Conduct Standard
will reduce regulatory uncertainty and
promote network investment and
service-related innovation. As we
discussed above, regulatory uncertainty
serves as a major barrier to investment
and innovation. The record reflects that
ISPs and edge providers of all sizes have
foregone and are likely to forgo or delay
innovative service offerings or different
pricing plans that benefit consumers,
citing regulatory uncertainty under the
Internet Conduct Standard in particular.
Indeed, these harms are not limited to
ISPs—the rule ‘‘creates paralyzing
uncertainty for app developers and
other edge providers,’’ as well as
equipment manufacturers. Even some
proponents of Title II acknowledge
these public interest harms.
Commenters also note that ‘‘money
spent on backward-looking regulatory
compliance is money not spent on more
productive uses, such as investments in
broadband plant and services.’’ We
anticipate that eliminating the Internet
Conduct Standard will benefit
consumers, increase competition, and
eliminate regulatory uncertainty that
has ‘‘a corresponding chilling effect on
broadband investment and innovation.’’
231. The now-rescinded Zero-Rating
Report issued by the Wireless
Telecommunications Bureau illustrates
the uncertainty ISPs experience as a
result of the Internet Conduct Standard
adopted in the Title II Order. As
described in the Report, ‘‘zero-rated’’
content, applications, and services are
those that end users can access without
the data consumed being counted
toward the usage allowances or data
caps imposed by an operator’s service
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
plans. But following a thirteen-month
investigation during which providers
were left uncertain about whether their
zero-rating practices complied with the
Internet Conduct Standard, the Report
still did not identify specific evidence of
harm from particular zero-rating
programs that increased the amount of
data that consumers could use or
provide certainty about whether
particular zero-rating programs were
legally permissible. Instead, it offered a
‘‘set of overall considerations’’ that it
said would help ISPs assess whether a
particular zero-rating plan violates the
Title II Order. The now-rescinded ZeroRating Report demonstrated that under
the Internet Conduct Standard ISPs have
faced two options: Either wait for a
regulatory enforcement action that
could arrive at some unspecified future
point or stop providing consumers with
innovative offerings.
232. We anticipate that eliminating
the vague Internet Conduct Standard
will also lower compliance and other
related costs. The uncertainty
surrounding the rule ‘‘establishes a
standard for behavior that virtually
requires advice of counsel before a
single decision is made’’ and raises
‘‘costs [especially for smaller ISPs that]
struggle to understand its application to
their service prices, terms, conditions,
and practices.’’ Smaller ISPs contend
that they cannot ‘‘afford to be the
subject of enforcement actions by the
Commission or defend themselves
before the Commission as a result of
consumer complaints, because the costs
of having to defend their actions before
the Commission in Washington are
enormous, relative to their resources.’’
ISPs ‘‘that are required to defend
themselves against arbitrary
enforcement actions and/or frivolous
complaints will not have the time or
financial resources to invest in their
business. The costs of such compliance
will likely be passed onto consumers via
higher prices and/or limited service
offerings and upgrades.’’ The record
reflects widespread agreement from
commenters with otherwise-divergent
views that the Internet Conduct
Standard creates significant harm
without countervailing benefits.
233. We are further persuaded that the
advisory opinion process introduced in
the Title II Order ‘‘offers no real relief
from the unintended consequences of
the Internet Conduct Standard.’’ The
record reflects that the Internet Conduct
Standard and the advisory opinions
available under it ‘‘[are] completely
divorced from the rapid pace of
innovation in the mobile marketplace’’
because ISP innovations would be
indefinitely delayed while the
PO 00000
Frm 00048
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
Commission conducts a searching
analysis of any such offering that might
violate the standard. The fact that no
ISP has requested an advisory opinion
in the two years since the launch of the
advisory opinion process reinforces our
conclusion that the process is too
uncertain and costly. As such, we reject
commenters’ assertions to the contrary.
b. Paid Prioritization
234. We also decline to adopt a ban
on paid prioritization. The transparency
rule we adopt, along with enforcement
of the antitrust and consumer protection
laws, addresses many of the concerns
regarding paid prioritization raised in
this record. Thus, the incremental
benefit of a ban on paid prioritization is
likely to be small or zero. On the other
hand, we expect that eliminating the
ban on paid prioritization will help spur
innovation and experimentation,
encourage network investment, and
better allocate the costs of
infrastructure, likely benefiting
consumers and competition. For these
reasons and because we find that
eliminating the ban on paid
prioritization arrangements could lead
to lower prices for consumers for
broadband internet access service, we
find that our action benefits low-income
communities and non-profits, and we
reject arguments to the contrary. We
reject the argument that the benefits of
our elimination of the paid
prioritization ban must be ‘‘uniform
across providers or geographic areas.’’
This is an unnecessarily high and rigid
threshold. The public—including lowincome communities—benefits, and that
is enough. Thus, the costs (forgone
benefits) of the ban are likely significant
and outweigh any incremental benefits
of a ban on paid prioritization.
235. Innovation. We anticipate that
lifting the ban on paid prioritization
will increase network innovation, as the
record demonstrates that the ban on
paid prioritization agreements has had,
and will continue to have, a chilling
effect on network innovation generally,
and on the development of high qualityof-service (QoS) arrangements—which
require guarantees regarding packet loss,
packet delay, secure connectivity, and
guaranteed bandwidth—in particular.
As CTIA argues, the Title II Order
implicitly recognized this point, but its
insistence that these arrangements be
treated as non-broadband internet
access data services reduced the
flexibility of ISPs and edge providers,
created uncertainty about the line
between non-broadband internet access
data services and broadband internet
access services, and likely reduced
innovation. The record reflects that the
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
ban on paid prioritization has hindered
the deployment of these services by
denying network operators the ability to
price these services, an important tool
for appropriately allocating resources in
a market economy. We reject commenter
assertions that banning the use of price
as a signal provides more accurate price
signals. Relatedly, we reject the
argument that non-price signals,
including user-directed prioritization,
are by themselves sufficient to allow
innovation and development in this
area, because in a market system, price
signals are generally necessary to
efficiently allocate resources. Further, as
commenters note, there has been
significant uncertainty about the scope
of the prohibition on paid prioritization
arrangements. Some commenters
contend that this uncertainty
surrounding network operators’ ability
to provide ‘‘differentiated services’’ has
cast a shadow on the development of
next generation networks.
236. We also expect that ending the
flat ban on paid prioritization will
encourage the entry of new edge
providers into the market, particularly
those offering innovative forms of
service differentiation and
experimentation. As ITTA explains, ‘‘[i]t
is routine for entities that do business
over the internet to pay for a variety of
services to provide an optimal user
experience for their customers.
Companies have been doing so for years
without disturbing the thriving internet
ecosystem.’’ We therefore reject
arguments that the ban is necessary to
provide a level playing field for edge
providers. Indeed, in other areas of the
economy, paid prioritization has helped
the entry of new providers and brands.
It is therefore no surprise that paid
prioritization has long been used
throughout the economy. Paid
prioritization could allow small and
new edge providers to compete on a
more even playing field against large
edge providers, many of which have
CDNs and other methods of distributing
their content quickly to consumers. We
thus reject arguments that allowing procompetitive paid prioritization will
reduce the entry and expansion of
small, new edge providers. In so
finding, we do not mean to suggest that
CDN services themselves constitute paid
prioritization.
237. Efficiency. We find that a ban on
paid prioritization is also likely to
reduce economic efficiency, also likely
harming consumer welfare. This finding
is supported by the economic literature
on two-sided markets such as this one,
and the record. If an ISP faces
competitive forces, a prohibition against
two-sided pricing (i.e., a zero-price
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
rule), while benefiting edge providers,
typically would harm both subscribers
and ISPs. Moreover, the level of harm to
subscribers and ISPs generally would
exceed the gain obtained by the edge
providers and, thus, would lead to a
reduction in total economic welfare.
The reasons for this are straightforward.
Some edge services and their associated
end users use more data or require
lower latency; this may be the case, for
example, with high-bandwidth
applications such as Netflix, which in
the first half of 2016 generated more
than a third of all North American
internet traffic. Without paid
prioritization, ISPs must recover these
costs solely from end users, but ISPs
cannot always set prices targeted at the
relevant end users. The resulting prices
create inefficiencies. Consumers who do
not cause these costs must pay for them,
and end users who do cause these costs
to some degree free-ride, inefficiently
distorting usage of both groups. When
paid prioritization signals to edge
providers the costs their content or
applications cause, edge providers can
undertake actions that would improve
the efficiency of the two-sided market.
For example, they could invest in
compression technologies if those come
at a lower cost than paid prioritization,
enhancing efficiency, or, if they have a
pricing relationship with their end
users, they could directly charge the end
user for priority, leading those end users
to adjust their usage if the user’s value
does not exceed the service’s cost, again
enhancing economic efficiency. We
disagree with commenters asserting that
this is likely to significantly burden
edge providers by requiring them to
negotiate with hundreds of ISPs because
as discussed, paid prioritization is likely
to be focused only on applications that
require special QoS guarantees. And to
the extent an ISP has market power,
antitrust and consumer protection laws
could be used to address ISPs’ anticompetitive paid prioritization
practices. Given the extent of
competition in internet access supply,
we find a ban on paid prioritization is
unlikely to improve economic
efficiency, and if it were to do so it
would only be by accident (i.e., if the
efficient second-best was to require ISPs
to provide access to edge providers at a
zero price).
238. Network investment. The mere
possibility that charging edge providers
may sometimes be economically
inefficient is not sufficient to overcome
the general presumption that allowing
firms additional pricing tools generally
enhances economic efficiency,
especially when investments must be
PO 00000
Frm 00049
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
7899
made as demand rises to reduce
congestion. The economic literature and
the record both suggest that paid
prioritization can increase network
investment. For example, one study
presents a model in which two
competing ISPs serve a continuum of
edge providers. It finds that allowing
ISPs to offer paid prioritization leads to
higher investment in broadband
capacity as well as greater innovation on
the edge provider side of the market.
According to the authors, paid
prioritization causes the ISP to invest
more in network capacity, reducing
congestion and thereby inducing
congestion-sensitive edge providers to
enter the market. The increased ISP
investment occurs for two reasons:
Incremental investment is more
profitable because the ISP can now
charge edge providers in addition to
subscribers, and paid prioritization
allows more edge providers who need a
high quality of service to enter the
market. Another study also develops a
theoretical model in which paid
prioritization always results in higher
ISP investment. We anticipate that
lifting the ban on paid prioritization
may also increase the entry of new ISPs
and encourage current providers to
expand their networks by making it
easier for ‘‘ISPs [to] benefit from their
new investments.’’ Thus, we reject the
argument that the ban is necessary to
ensure long-term network investment.
239. We reject assertions that allowing
paid prioritization would lead ISPs to
create artificial scarcity on their
networks by neglecting or downgrading
non-paid traffic. This argument has been
strongly criticized as having ‘‘no
support in economic theory that such
incentives exist or are sufficiently strong
as to outweigh countervailing
incentives.’’ Moreover, as discussed
above, in practice paid prioritization is
likely to be used to deliver enhanced
service for applications that need QoS
guarantees. As AT&T explains, ‘‘[l]astmile access is not a zero-sum game, and
prioritizing the packets for latencysensitive applications will not typically
degrade other applications sharing the
same infrastructure,’’ such as email,
software updates, or cached video. We
thus reject arguments premised on the
theory that ISPs could and would act to
create artificial scarcity on their
networks and thereby broadly require
paid prioritization. Because of these
practical limits on paid prioritization,
we reject the argument that non-profits
and independent and diverse content
producers, who may be less likely to
need QoS guarantees, will be harmed by
lifting the ban.
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
7900
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
240. Reduction in price to consumers.
Eliminating the ban on paid
prioritization arrangements could lead
to lower prices for consumers for
broadband internet access service, as
ISPs may be able to recoup some of their
costs from edge providers. Although we
do not premise our analysis on the
expectation of a total pass-through of
these revenues to end-users, we find no
support for assumptions that there
would be no pass-through of revenues at
all. As one study explains, the Title II
Order’s ban on paid prioritization
arrangements ‘‘can lead to higher prices
that are charged to all end users—
regardless of whether or not the end
user subscribes to the content service
that causes the congestion.’’
241. Closing the digital divide. Paid
prioritization can also be a tool in
helping close the digital divide by
reducing broadband internet access
service subscription prices for
consumers. The zero-price rule imposed
by the blanket ban on paid prioritization
‘‘imposes a regressive subsidy,
transferring wealth from the
economically disadvantaged to the
comparatively rich by forcing the poor
to support high-bandwidth subscription
services skewed towards the wealthier.’’
One study concludes that ‘‘[a]t the
margin, this would cause the lowest-end
users to simply stop subscribing to
internet services, which would further
exacerbate the existing digital divide.’’
Accordingly, economic ‘‘models . . .
suggest that network neutrality
regulation is more likely to worsen than
improve the digital divide.’’ Because
ending the ban on paid prioritization is
likely to help close the digital divide,
we reject assertions to the contrary that
ending the paid prioritization rule’s
effective subsidization of highbandwidth services will harm
consumers overall. We reject the
contrary argument that ISPs will engage
in ‘‘virtual redlining’’ because, as
discussed, paid prioritization is likely to
lead to increased network investment
and lower costs to end users,
particularly benefiting those on the
wrong side of the digital divide.
Allowing ISPs to charge both sides of
the market could also enable additional
arrangements to provide special lowcost broadband access, increasing
broadband adoption among lowerincome consumers. For example,
permitting ‘‘differential pricing’’ may
enable the development of ‘‘[p]latforms
that are both free and tailored to [people
without internet access],’’ similar to
Facebook’s Free Basics program in
developing countries. Nokia suggests
that ‘‘a start-up company that wants to
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
reach new customers with a bandwidth
intensive application that will not work
as intended below a certain service tier
. . . should be allowed to offer to boost
[a] consumer’s bandwidth so he or she
can experience their product as
intended,’’ and argues such
arrangements ‘‘are most likely to benefit
lower-income consumers, since those
that already purchase high-tier services
are less likely to benefit from thirdparty-pays QoS enhancements.’’
242. Addressing Harms. We find that
antitrust law, in combination with the
transparency rule we adopt, is
particularly well-suited to addressing
any potential or actual anticompetitive
harms that may arise from paid
prioritization arrangements. The
transparency rule will require ISPs to
disclose any practices that favor some
internet traffic over other traffic, if the
practices are paid or benefit any
affiliated entity. The transparency rule
will provide greater information to all
participants in the internet ecosystem
and empower them to act if they
identify any potential anticompetitive
conduct. Antitrust law is ideally
situated to determine whether a specific
arrangement, on balance, is anticompetitive or pro-competitive. We
therefore reject the argument that the
paid prioritization ban should be
modified to more squarely focus on
anticompetitive conduct. While these
alternative formulations may not be as
problematic as the blanket ban, for the
reasons discussed above, antitrust law is
better placed than ex ante regulations to
balance the potential benefits and harms
of new arrangements. Moreover, to the
extent that they exist, the potential
harms to internet openness stemming
from paid prioritization arrangements
are outweighed by the distortions that
banning paid prioritization would
impose. Under the antitrust laws, a paid
prioritization agreement challenged as
anticompetitive would be evaluated
under the case-specific rule of reason.
Paid prioritization would be prohibited
only when it harms competition, for
example, by inappropriately favoring an
affiliate or partner in a way that
ultimately harms economic competition
in the relevant market. The case-by-case,
deliberative nature of antitrust is wellsuited for this area, as it is difficult to
determine on an ex ante basis which
paid prioritization agreements are
anticompetitive, and in fact, no internet
paid prioritization agreements have yet
been launched in the United States,
rendering any concerns about such
practices purely theoretical at this time.
We therefore reject arguments that ex
ante rules are preferable.
PO 00000
Frm 00050
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
243. Lastly, antitrust laws would not
prevent an ISP from exercising legallyacquired market power to earn market
rents, so long as it is not used
anticompetitively, but we do not
consider any harms that might result
from this to be so large as to justify the
harms that a total prohibition on paid
prioritization would entail. For harms
from the exercise of legally-acquired
market power to arise, the ISP must
have market power over the edge
provider. However, as shown above,
ISPs usually face at least moderate
competition, and all the more so taking
a medium-term perspective.
Consequently, the harms that could
possibly occur from exercise of such
power are not likely to be large. Further,
the extent to which any harms actually
occur will be muted by two factors.
First, ISPs have strong incentives to
keep edge provider output high (as this
increases the value end users see in
subscribing to the ISP, and signals to
edge providers that the ISP recognizes
their contribution to the platform).
Thus, harm will only occur to the extent
the ISP is unable to devise pricing
schemes that preserve edge providers’
incentives to bring content while
maximizing the ISP’s profit (the exercise
of market power is only harmful when
it excludes what would otherwise be
efficient purchases of access). Second,
as discussed above, increased prices
from edge providers are to a potentially
significant extent passed through to end
users in the form of lower prices for
broadband internet access service, with
the result that end user demand for edge
provider content is increased. The
extent of such pass-through offsets these
harms. Accordingly, we expect the
harms from dictating pricing uniformity
to edge providers exceed any harms that
may emerge from a lack of such
regulation.
c. Blocking and Throttling
244. We find the no-blocking and nothrottling rules are unnecessary to
prevent the harms that they were
intended to thwart. We find that the
transparency rule we adopt today—
coupled with our enforcement authority
and with FTC enforcement of ISP
commitments, antitrust law, consumer
expectations, and ISP incentives—will
be sufficient to prevent these harms,
particularly given the consensus against
blocking practices, as reflected in the
scarcity of actual cases of such blocking.
For the same reasons, we reject
alternative formulations of the noblocking and no-throttling rules.
245. Transparency rule. As discussed
above, the transparency rule we adopt,
combined with antitrust and consumer
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
protection laws, obviate the need for
conduct rules by achieving comparable
benefits at lower cost. In addition,
several factors specific to blocking and
throttling will work to prevent the
potential harms that could be caused by
blocking and throttling. First, most
attempts by ISPs to block or throttle
content will likely be met with a fierce
consumer backlash. As one commenter
explains, such blocking or throttling is
‘‘unlikely to occur, because it must be
sufficiently blatant to be of any benefit
to the ISP, that [it] only increases the
likelihood of getting caught.’’ Second,
numerous ISPs, including the four
largest fixed ISPs, have publicly
committed not to block or throttle the
content that consumers choose. The
transparency rule will ensure that ISPs
reveal any deviation from these
commitments to the public, and
addresses commenter concerns that
consumers will not understand the
source of any blocking or throttling.
Violations of the transparency rule will
be subject to our enforcement authority.
Furthermore, the FTC possesses the
authority to enforce these commitments,
as it did in TracFone. Third, the
antitrust laws prohibit anticompetitive
conduct, and to the extent blocking or
throttling by an ISP may constitute such
conduct, the existence of these laws
likely deters potentially anticompetitive
conduct. Finally, ISPs have long-term
incentives to preserve internet
openness, which creates demand for the
internet access service that they
provide.
246. Consensus against blocking and
throttling. We emphasize once again
that we do not support blocking lawful
content, consistent with long-standing
Commission policy. The potential
consequences of blocking or throttling
lawful content on the internet
ecosystem are well-documented in the
record and in Commission precedent.
Stakeholders from across the internet
ecosystem oppose the blocking and
throttling of lawful content, including
ISPs, public interest groups, edge
providers, other content producers,
network equipment manufacturers,
government entities, and other
businesses and individuals who use the
internet. This consensus is among the
reasons that there is scant evidence that
end users, under different legal
frameworks, have been prevented by
blocking or throttling from accessing the
content of their choosing. It also is
among the reasons why providers have
voluntarily abided by no-blocking
practices even during periods where
they were not legally required to do so.
As to free expression in particular, we
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
note that none of the actual incidents
discussed in the Title II Order squarely
implicated free speech. If anything,
recent evidence suggests that hosting
services, social media platforms, edge
providers, and other providers of virtual
internet infrastructure are more likely to
block content on viewpoint grounds.
Furthermore, in the event that any
stakeholder were inclined to deviate
from this consensus against blocking
and throttling, we fully expect that
consumer expectations, market
incentives, and the deterrent threat of
enforcement actions will constrain such
practices ex ante. To the extent that
these incentives prove insufficient and
any stakeholder engages in such
conduct, such practices can be policed
ex post by antitrust and consumer
protection agencies.
247. Additionally, as urged by the
prior Commission when defending the
Title II Order, and as confirmed in the
concurrence in the denial of rehearing
en banc by the two judges in the
majority in USTelecom, the Title II
Order allows ISPs to offer curated
services, which would allow ISPs to
escape the reach of the Title II Order
and to filter content on viewpoint
grounds. In practice, the Title II Order
‘‘deregulates curated Internet access
relative to conventional Internet access
[and] may induce ISPs to filter content
more often,’’ rendering the no-blocking
and no-throttling rules ineffectual as
long as an ISP disclosed it was offering
curated services. The curated services
exemption arising from the Title II
Order confirms our judgment that
transparency requirements, rather than
conduct rules, are the most effective
means of preserving internet openness.
3. The Record Does Not Identify
Authority for Comprehensive Conduct
Rules
248. The record in this proceeding
does not persuade us that there are any
sources of statutory authority that
individually, or in the aggregate, could
support conduct rules uniformly
encompassing all ISPs. We find that
provisions in Section 706 of the 1996
Act directing the Commission to
encourage deployment of advanced
telecommunications capability are
better interpreted as hortatory rather
than as independent grants of regulatory
authority. We also are not persuaded
that Section 230 of the Communications
Act is a grant of regulatory authority
that could provide the basis for conduct
rules here. Nor does the record here
reveal other sources of authority that
collectively would provide a sure
foundation for conduct rules that would
PO 00000
Frm 00051
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
7901
treat all similarly-situated ISPs the
same.
a. Section 706 of the 1996 Act
249. We conclude that the directives
to the Commission in Section 706(a) and
(b) of the 1996 Act to promote
deployment of advanced
telecommunications capability are
better interpreted as hortatory, and not
as grants of regulatory authority. We
thus depart from the interpretation of
those provisions adopted by the
Commission beginning in the Open
Internet Order, and return to a reading
of that language in Section 706 of the
1996 Act consistent with the
Commission’s original interpretation.
250. We adopt this reading in light of
the text, structure, and history of the
1996 Act and Communications Act.
Section 706(a) directs that:
The Commission and each State
commission with regulatory jurisdiction over
telecommunications services shall encourage
the deployment on a reasonable and timely
basis of advanced telecommunications
capability to all Americans (including, in
particular, elementary and secondary schools
and classrooms) by utilizing, in a manner
consistent with the public interest,
convenience, and necessity, price cap
regulation, regulatory forbearance, measures
that promote competition in the local
telecommunications market, or other
regulating methods that remove barriers to
infrastructure investment.
In turn, Section 706(b) provides in
pertinent part that ‘‘[i]f the
Commission’s determination’’ under an
annual inquiry into deployment of
advanced telecommunications
capability ‘‘is negative, it shall take
immediate action to accelerate
deployment of such capability by
removing barriers to infrastructure
investment and by promoting
competition in the telecommunications
market.’’
251. The relevant text of Section
706(a) and (b) of the 1996 Act is
reasonably read as exhorting the
Commission to exercise market-based or
deregulatory authority granted under
other statutory provisions, particularly
the Communications Act. The
Commission otherwise has authority
under the Communications Act to
employ price cap regulation for services
subject to rate regulation; to employ
regulatory forbearance; to promote
competition in the local
telecommunications market; and to
remove barriers to infrastructure
investment. The Commission thus need
not interpret Section 706 as an
independent grant of regulatory
authority to give those provisions
meaning. Further, consistent with
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
7902
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
normal canons of statutory
interpretation, the language ‘‘other
regulating methods’’ in Section 706(a) is
best understood as consistent with the
language that precedes it, and thus
likewise reasonably is read as focused
on the exercise of other statutory
authority like that under the
Communications Act, rather than itself
constituting an independent grant of
regulatory authority. This view also
comports with the Commission’s
original interpretation of the language of
Section 706(a), avoids rendering the
provisions of Section 706(a) or (b)
surplusage, and does not otherwise
conflict with the statutory text.
Although the term ‘‘shall’’ ‘‘generally
indicates a command that admits of no
discretion,’’ because the Commission
has other authority under the
Communications Act that it can exercise
consistent with the direction in Section
706(a) and (b) of the 1996 Act, our
interpretation is not at odds with the
use of ‘‘shall encourage’’ in Section
706(a) or ‘‘shall take immediate action’’
in Section 706(b). In particular, Section
706(a) provides a general, ongoing
exhortation for the Commission to
encourage deployment of advanced
telecommunications capability through
exercise of other authority, while
Section 706(b) directs the Commission
to do so by taking ‘‘immediate action’’
in the event of a negative finding under
the Section 706(b) inquiry. The
direction in Section 706(b) of the 1996
Act that the Commission exercise other
authority by taking ‘‘immediate action’’
in the event of a negative finding under
the Section 706(b) inquiry could, for
example, form part of the basis for
petition(s) for Commission rulemaking
based on such other authority in the
wake of a negative finding in the
Section 706(b) inquiry. Although the
Tenth Circuit concluded that the
possibility of such an interpretation of
Section 706(b) would not
unambiguously compel the conclusion
that the provision is hortatory, the
court’s decision does not limit our
ability to rely on that as a factor that
persuades us that Section 706(b) is
better read as hortatory.
252. We not only find that the
relevant language in Sections 706(a) and
(b) of the 1996 Act permissibly can be
read as hortatory, but are persuaded that
is the better interpretation. Arguments
in the record supporting Section 706 of
the 1996 Act as granting regulatory
authority generally contend that this is
a permissible interpretation but do not
persuade us it is the better reading. For
one, although the relevant provisions in
Section 706(a) and (b) identify certain
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
regulatory tools (like price cap
regulation and regulatory forbearance)
and marketplace outcomes (like
increased competition and reduced
barriers to infrastructure investment),
they nowhere identify the providers or
entities whose conduct could be
regulated under Section 706 if
interpreted as a grant of such authority.
This lack of detail stands in stark
contrast to Congress’s approach in many
other provisions enacted or modified as
part of the 1996 Act that clearly are
grants of authority to employ similar
regulatory tools or pursue similar
marketplace outcomes and that directly
identify the relevant providers or
entities subject to the exercise of that
regulatory authority. The absence of any
similar language in Section 706(a) and
(b) of the 1996 Act supports our view
that those provisions are better read as
directing the Commission regarding its
exercise of regulatory authority granted
elsewhere. Our consideration of this as
one factor persuading us that Section
706 of the 1996 Act is better read as
hortatory is not undercut by our reliance
on Section 257 as authority for
disclosure requirements that provide us
information needed to identify potential
barriers to entry and investment while
also helping mitigate any such barriers.
Although Section 257 does not
expressly identify entities from which
we can obtain information, other aspects
of Section 257 persuade us that our
interpretation of that provision as a
grant of authority to obtain the
information we require from ISPs is
necessary for us to carry out our duties
under that provision for the reasons
discussed above. Here, by contrast, this
consideration combines with many
others to collectively persuade us that
Section 706 of the 1996 Act is better
read as hortatory.
253. Indeed, under the Open Internet
Order’s theory of Section 706(a) and (b)
as independent grants of authority, the
Commission could rely on those
provisions to impose duties or adopt
regulations equivalent to those directly
addressed by the provisions of the
Communications Act focused on
promoting competition and/or
deployment that go beyond the entities,
contexts, and circumstances that
bounded the Communications Act
provisions. Section 706(a) and (b) direct
the Commission to promote competition
in the local telecommunications market
and otherwise encourage the
deployment of advanced
telecommunications capability.
Promoting local competition and/or
encouraging the deployment of
telecommunications networks likewise
PO 00000
Frm 00052
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
are key objectives of a number of
provisions added to the
Communications Act by the 1996 Act,
each of which were limited in scope to
address the actions of particular,
defined entities and were triggered in
particular, defined circumstances. For
example, the 1996 Act amended Section
224 of the Communications Act to
expand specified communications
providers’ access to utilities’ poles,
ducts, conduit, and rights-of-way to
‘‘ensure that the deployment of
communications networks and the
development of competition are not
impeded by private ownership and
control of the scarce infrastructure and
rights-of-way that many
communications providers must use in
order to reach customers.’’ The marketopening framework in Sections 251(a)–
(c), 252, and 271 of the Communications
Act, applicable respectively to
telecommunications carriers, LECs,
incumbent LECs, and BOCs, also were
added by the 1996 Act. The 1996 Act
also added provisions to the
Communications Act to eliminate
regulatory barriers to competition and
network deployment in certain defined
circumstances. We are skeptical that at
the same time Congress enacted
carefully-tailored regulatory regimes
codified in various provisions of the
Communications Act, it simultaneously
granted the Commission redundant
authority to impose those same duties or
adopt similar regulatory treatment
largely unbound by that tailoring in a
‘‘Miscellaneous’’ provision of the same
legislation.
254. Our interpretation of Section 706
of the 1996 Act as hortatory also is
supported by the implications of the
Open Internet Order’s interpretation for
the regulatory treatment of the internet
and information services more
generally. The interpretation of Section
706(a) and (b) that the Commission
adopted beginning in the Open Internet
Order reads those provisions to grant
authority for the Commission to regulate
information services so long as doing so
could be said to encourage deployment
of advanced telecommunications
capability at least indirectly. A reading
of Section 706 as a grant of regulatory
authority that could be used to heavily
regulate information services—as under
the Commission’s prior interpretation—
is undercut by what the Commission
has found to be Congress’ intent in other
provisions of the Communications Act
enacted in the 1996 Act—namely, to
distinguish between
telecommunications services and
information services, with the latter left
largely unregulated by default.
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
255. In addition, the 1996 Act added
Section 230 of the Communications Act,
which provides, among other things,
that ‘‘[i]t is the policy of the United
States . . . to preserve the vibrant and
competitive free market that presently
exists for the internet and other
interactive computer services,
unfettered by Federal or State
regulation.’’ The Open Internet Order
asserted that ‘‘[m]aximizing end-user
control is a policy goal Congress
recognized in Section 230(b) of the
Communications Act.’’ In full, however,
Section 230(b)(3) states that ‘‘[i]t is the
policy of the United States—. . . to
encourage the development of
technologies which maximize user
control over what information is
received by individuals, families, and
schools who use the Internet and other
interactive computer services.’’
Although the rules in the Open Internet
Order would have considered the extent
to which a network management
practice is subject to end-user control
when evaluating the reasonableness of
discrimination, that Order does not
explain why that (or conduct rules more
generally) would better encourage the
development of technologies for enduser control than would be the case
without such rules. The Title II Order is
similar in this regard. Assertions of the
sort in those Orders thus provide no
basis for concluding that regulating ISPs
is likely to better ‘‘encourage the
development of technologies which
maximize user control’’ than the
absence of such regulations. A necessary
implication of the prior interpretation of
Section 706(a) and (b) as grants of
regulatory authority is that the
Commission could regulate not only
ISPs but also edge providers or other
participants in the internet
marketplace—even when they
constitute information services, and
notwithstanding Section 230 of the
Communications Act—so long as the
Commission could find at least an
indirect nexus to promoting the
deployment of advanced
telecommunications capability. For
example, some commenters argue that
‘‘it is content aggregators (think Netflix,
Etsy, Google, Facebook) that probably
exert the greatest, or certainly the most
direct, influence over access.’’ Section
230 likewise is in tension with the view
that Section 706(a) and (b) grant the
Commission regulatory authority as the
Commission previously claimed. These
inconsistencies are avoided, however, if
the deployment directives of Section
706(a) and (b) are viewed as hortatory.
256. Prior Commission guidance
regarding how it would interpret and
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
apply the authority it claimed under
Section 706(a) and (b) of the 1996 Act
does not allay our concerns with the
interpretation of those provisions as
grants of regulatory authority. For
example, the Open Internet Order stated
that Section 706 authority only would
be used to regulate ‘‘communication by
wire or radio,’’ consistent with Sections
1 and 2 of the Communications Act.
Other provisions enacted in the 1996
Act that clearly grant authority to
promote competition or network
deployment themselves generally
address either facilities being used to
engage in communications or the
communications themselves, however.
Thus, applying Section 706 of the 1996
Act only to communication by wire or
radio would not prevent the
Commission from replicating such
requirements. In addition, broadband
internet access service itself involves
communications by wire or radio—as do
many other internet information
services. Consequently, this
Commission guidance also does not
resolve tensions between the
Commission’s prior theory of Section
706 authority and the 1996 Act’s general
deregulatory approach to information
services or Section 230’s enunciation of
the federal policy ‘‘to preserve the
vibrant and competitive free market that
presently exists for the Internet and
other interactive computer services,
unfettered by Federal or State
regulation.’’
257. Nor are the specific, problematic
implications we identify with the
Commission’s prior interpretation of
Section 706 as a grant of authority
avoided by the Commission’s
explanation that its use of such
authority must encourage the
deployment of advanced
telecommunications capability by
promoting competition or removing
barriers to infrastructure investment.
Given the already-recognized nexus
between the relevant Communications
Act provisions and the promotion of
network deployment and/or local
competition, the record provides no
reason to believe the Commission would
have difficulty demonstrating at least an
indirect effect on the deployment of
advanced telecommunications
capability should it wish, as a policy
matter, to impose equivalent
requirements under an assertion of
authority under Section 706(a) and (b)
without adhering to limitations or
constraints present in the
Communications Act provisions.
Perhaps if the Commission required a
tighter connection between a given
regulatory action and promoting
PO 00000
Frm 00053
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
7903
deployment of advanced
telecommunications capability, it might
reduce the magnitude of the
inconsistency somewhat, but the record
does not reveal that such an approach
would eliminate it entirely or even
diminish it to such an extent as to
materially strengthen the argument for
interpreting the relevant provisions of
Section 706(a) and (b) as grants of
regulatory authority. Such proposals
also do not address the other reasons for
viewing Sections 706(a) and (b) as
hortatory in light of the statutory text
and structure. Likewise, the Open
Internet Order shows that the
Commission can readily find that
criterion met in order to regulate an
information service like broadband
internet access service notwithstanding
the 1996 Act’s general deregulatory
approach for information service and
the deregulatory internet policy
specified in Section 230 of the Act.
258. Guidance in the Open Internet
Order also asserted that the exercise of
Section 706 authority could not be
‘‘inconsistent with other provisions of
law,’’ but effectively viewed that as a
very low bar to satisfy, finding it
reasonable to exercise Section 706
authority to impose duties on
information service providers that did
not meaningfully ‘‘differ[ ] from the
nondiscrimination standard applied to
common carriers generally.’’ So long as
regulations fall outside the constraints
of Sections 3(51) and 332(c)(2) of the
Act—upon which the reversal in
Verizon was based—neither precedent
nor the record here demonstrate that the
reference to ensuring that any Section
706 authority be exercised ‘‘[ ]consistent
with other provisions of law’’ would
meaningfully preclude the types of
requirements that we find difficult to
square with the carefully tailored
authority in the Communications Act.
Conversely, if the fact that a matter is
addressed by the Communications Act
were a more serious constraint on
claimed Section 706(a) and (b)
authority, it is unclear how meaningful
such claimed authority would be in
practice. It thus likewise would be
unclear what affirmative reason we
would have for interpreting them as
grants of authority contrary to the other
indicia that they are hortatory. For
example, Sections 201(b) and 202(a) of
the Act prohibit unjust and
unreasonable rates and practices and
unjust an unreasonable discrimination
with respect to common carrier services.
If that precluded reliance on Section
706(a) and (b) to impose analogous
restrictions unbounded by the selfdescribed scope of Sections 201(b) and
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
7904
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
202(a), the Commission seemingly
would be left with no authority to adopt
conduct rules of the sort at issue here
after reclassification. Nor do
commenters citing other possible uses of
Section 706(a) and (b) as authority
explain how such exercise of authority
could be reconciled with the view that
it would be a serious constraint on
claimed Section 706(a) and (b) authority
if a matter is addressed by the
Communications Act (such as in
Sections 201 and 202, the marketopening provisions in Sections 251–261,
provisions designed to address barriers
to infrastructure deployment like
Sections 224 and 254, or other
provisions). Thus, interpreting the
Communications Act as a more serious
constraint might partially address one
basis for interpreting Section 706(a) and
(b) as hortatory, but simultaneously
would undercut the arguments in the
record for interpreting them as grants of
authority.
259. We also are unpersuaded by the
Open Internet Order’s citation of
legislative history to support its
interpretation of Section 706(a) and (b)
as grants of regulatory authority. The
Open Internet Order cited a Senate
report for the proposition that those
provisions of Section 706 ‘‘are ‘a
necessary fail-safe’ to guarantee that
Congress’s objective is reached.’’ The
Commission itself previously noted the
ambiguous significance of that language.
In addition, the relevant Senate bill at
the time of the Senate report would
have directed the Commission, in the
event of a negative finding in its
deployment inquiry, to ‘‘take immediate
action under this section’’ and stated
that ‘‘it may preempt State commissions
that fail to act to ensure such
availability.’’ The final, enacted version
of Section 706(b), by contrast, omitted
the language ‘‘under this section,’’ and
also omitted the express preemption
language, leaving it ambiguous whether
the statement in the Senate report was
premised on statutory language
excluded from the enacted provision.
For its part, the conference report
neither repeats the ‘‘fail-safe’’ language
from the Senate report nor elaborates on
the modifications made to the language
in the Senate bill. Even if it were
appropriate to consult legislative
history, we conclude that that history is
ultimately ambiguous and are not
persuaded that it supports interpreting
Section 706(a) and (b) of the 1996 Act
as grants of regulatory authority.
260. The inability to impose penalties
to enforce violations of requirements
adopted under Section 706(a) and (b) of
the 1996 Act also undercuts arguments
that those provisions should be
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
interpreted as grants of regulatory
authority. Section 706 of the 1996 Act
was not incorporated into the
Communications Act, nor does the 1996
Act provide for it to be enforced as part
of the Communications Act. Where
Congress intended a statute outside the
Communications Act to be enforced as
if it were part of the Communications
Act, it has expressly stated that in the
relevant statute. Thus, the
Communications Act provisions
generally authorizing penalties do not
apply to Section 706 of the 1996 Act or
rules adopted thereunder. In pertinent
part, to enforce rules under Section
503(b)(1) of the Communications Act,
the rules must be ‘‘issued by the
Commission under [the
Communications] Act.’’ Other penalty
provisions in the Communications Act
are specific to narrower topics or the
statutory section in which they appear,
and thus also would not be authorized
penalties for violations of rules
implementing Section 706 of the 1996
Act. Although the Title II Order claimed
that Section 706 of the 1996 Act
included an implicit grant of
enforcement authority, even under that
theory, an ‘implicit’ grant of
enforcement authority might enable
actions like declaratory rulings or ceaseand-desist orders, but would not appear
to encompass authority to impose
penalties given the absence of statutory
language clearly granting that authority.
As a fallback, the Title II Order asserted,
without elaboration, that by relying on
the grant of rulemaking authority in
Section 4(i) of the Communications Act
to adopt rules implementing Section
706 of the 1996 Act, the resulting rules
would be within the scope of those for
which forfeitures could be imposed
under the Communications Act.
261. We believe that the better view
is that reliance on the Communications
Act for rulemaking authority alone
would not render the resulting rules
‘‘issued by the Commission under [the
Communications] Act’’ as required to
trigger the forfeiture provisions of
Section 503 of the Act. Given that
Section 503 is about enforcement
consequences from violating standards
of conduct specified by, among other
things, relevant Commission rules, we
think that language is best read as
focused on rules implementing the
Commission’s substantive regulatory
authority under the Communications
Act. Insofar as the substantive standard
to which an entity is being held flows
not from the Communications Act but
from the Commission’s assertion of
authority under the 1996 Act, we
believe that our forfeiture authority
PO 00000
Frm 00054
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
under Section 503 of the
Communications Act consequently
would not encompass such rules. The
practical inability to back up rules
implementing Section 706 with
penalties thus undercuts the Open
Internet Order’s claim that its
interpretation would mean that Section
706 of the 1996 Act could serve as a
‘‘ ‘fail safe’ that ‘ensures’ the
Commission’s ability to promote
advanced services.’’ Under our
interpretation, by contrast, Section
706(a) and (b) of the 1996 Act exhort the
Commission to use Communications
Act authority that it does, in fact, have
authority to enforce through penalties.
We thus are persuaded that Section
706(a) and (b) of the 1996 Act are better
interpreted as hortatory, rather than as
grants of regulatory authority. Because
we otherwise find ample grounds to
conclude that Section 706(a) and (b) of
the 1996 Act are not grants of regulatory
authority, we need not, and thus do not,
address arguments claiming additional
reasons to reach that same conclusion.
Likewise, because we conclude that
Section 706(a) and (b) do not grant
regulatory authority at all, we need not,
and do not, address the issue of whether
any authority under those provisions is,
at most, deregulatory authority. We also
reject arguments that we should wait on
the completion of the latest inquiry
under Section 706(b) before evaluating
the interpretation of Section 706. Under
the prior interpretation, Section 706(a)
was a grant of authority independent of
Section 706(b), and particularly insofar
as we would not interpret Section
706(b) as a grant of authority in any
case, we see no reason to wait on the
results of the inquiry under that
provision.
262. Our conclusion that Section 706
of the 1996 Act is better read as
hortatory is not at odds with the fact
that two courts concluded that the
Commission permissibly could adopt
the alternative view that it is a grant of
regulatory authority. Those courts did
not find that the Commission’s previous
reading was the only (or even the most)
reasonable interpretation of Section 706,
leaving the Commission free to adopt a
different interpretation upon further
consideration. Indeed, the DC Circuit in
Verizon observed that the language of
Section 706(a) ‘‘certainly could be read’’
as hortatory. The court also recognized
as much with respect to Section 706(b),
given its lack of clarity. Those cases
thus leave us free to act on our
conclusion here that Section 706 is most
reasonably read as hortatory, not as an
independent grant of regulatory
authority.
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
263. We also disagree with arguments
that we should keep in place a
misguided and flawed interpretation of
Section 706(a) and (b) of the 1996 Act
to preserve any existing rules or our
ability going forward to take regulatory
action based on such assertions of
authority. We are not persuaded by
concerns that reinterpreting Section
706(a) and (b) of the 1996 Act in this
manner could undercut Commission
rules adopted in other contexts because
such arguments do not identify
circumstances—nor are we otherwise
aware of any—where the prior
interpretation of the relevant provisions
of Section 706(a) and/or (b) was, in
whole or in part, a necessary basis for
the rules. Similarly, concerns that our
interpretation will limit states’
regulatory authority do not identify with
specificity any concrete need for such
authority beyond any authority
provided by state law, even assuming
arguendo that such authority could have
flowed from the prior interpretation of
Section 706(a). MMTC and NABOB
express concerns that disavowing
Section 706 as a source of authority
could constrain the Commission’s
ability to address ‘‘digital redlining.’’
They do not explain, however, why
other statutory provisions such as
Section 254 are inadequate to address
issues of unserved or underserved
communities should more ultimately be
found to be needed beyond the
Commission’s other efforts to promote
broadband deployment more generally.
We also are unpersuaded by arguments
for maintaining the prior interpretation
in a general effort to retain greater
authority to regulate ISPs. Given that
agencies like the Commission are
creatures of Congress, and given our
responsibility to bring to bear
appropriate tools when interpreting and
implementing the statutes we
administer, we find it more appropriate
to adopt what we view as the far better
interpretation of Section 706(a) and (b)
given both the specific context of
Section 706 and the broader statutory
context. If Congress wishes to give the
Commission more explicit direction to
impose certain conduct rules on ISPs, or
to impose such rules itself within
constitutional limits, it is of course free
to do so. We decline to read such wideranging authority, however, into
provisions that, on our reading today,
are merely hortatory, and are at best
ambiguous.
264. Independently, we also are not
persuaded that the prior interpretation
of Section 706(a) and (b) of the 1996 Act
would better advance policy goals
relevant here. We have other sources of
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
authority on which to ground our
transparency requirements without
adopting an inferior interpretation of
Section 706(a) and (b). With respect to
conduct rules, in addition to our
decision that limits on our legal
authority counsel against adopting such
rules, we separately find that such rules
are not otherwise justified by the record
here. Consequently, we need not stretch
the words of Section 706 of the 1996 Act
because we can protect internet freedom
even without it. Rather, we are
persuaded to act in the manner that we
believe reflects the best interpretation
given the text and structure of the Act,
the legislative history, and the policy
implications of alternative
interpretations.
b. Section 230 of the Communications
Act
265. We are not persuaded that
Section 230 of the Communications Act
grants the Commission authority that
could provide the basis for conduct
rules here. In Comcast, the DC Circuit
observed that the Commission there
‘‘acknowledge[d] that Section 230(b)’’ is
a ‘‘statement [ ] of policy that [itself]
delegate[s] no regulatory authority.’’
Although the Internet Freedom NPRM
sought comment on Section 230, the
record does not reveal an alternative
interpretation that would enable us to
rely on it as a grant of regulatory
authority for rules here. Instead, we
remain persuaded that Section 230(b) is
hortatory, directing the Commission to
adhere to the policies specified in that
provision when otherwise exercising
our authority. In addition, even
assuming arguendo that Section 230
could be viewed as a grant of
Commission authority, we are not
persuaded it could be invoked to
impose regulatory obligations on ISPs.
In particular, Section 230(b)(2) provides
that it is U.S. policy ‘‘to preserve the
vibrant and competitive free market that
presently exists for the internet and
other interactive computer services,
unfettered by Federal or State
regulation.’’ Adopting requirements that
would impose federal regulation on
broadband internet access service would
be in tension with that policy, and we
thus are skeptical such requirements
could be justified by Section 230 even
if it were a grant of authority as relevant
here. Consequently, although Section
230 is relevant to our interpretation and
implementation of other statutory
provisions, the record does not reveal a
basis for relying on it as a source of
regulatory authority for conduct rules
here.
PO 00000
Frm 00055
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
7905
c. Other Provisions in Titles II, III, and
VI of the Communications Act
266. Other identified sources of
potential authority appear significantly
limited and not capable of bringing all
ISPs under one comprehensive
regulatory framework. The Open
Internet Order cited provisions in Titles
II, III, and VI of the Communications
Act in support of the conduct rules
adopted there, and some commenters
echo those theories—generally without
elaboration. Some comments identified
possible sources of authority for rules
other than the sorts of conduct rules at
issue in this proceeding, and we do not
discuss such other sources of authority
here. We also are not persuaded by
claims that Section 1 of the Act is a
grant of regulatory authority here. In
this very context, the DC Circuit has
held that Section 1 is better understood
as a statement of Congressional policy.
A number of those assertions of
authority appear of uncertain validity
on this record. The identified additional
sources of potential authority, even
collectively, do not appear to provide a
sound basis for conduct rules that
would encompass all ISPs. We do not
formally resolve the potential scope and
contours of those claims of authority
given the significant limitations in the
record here and the potential for
unanticipated spill-over effects, but the
potential weaknesses—unresolved on
this record—nonetheless make us
cautious about seeking to rely on them
at this time. Insofar as our position
regarding these additional potential
sources of authority is at least a partial
change in course from the positions
taken in the Open Internet Order—
which reflected a broader and/or less
questioning view of these theories—we
conclude that such a change in course
is warranted by our analysis here, which
identifies details or nuances in the
required analysis that were not
adequately addressed in the Open
Internet Order or resolved on this
record. Further, even as to those ISPs
that could be subject to conduct rules
under those statutory theories, in many
cases the scope of conduct that could be
addressed appears quite limited. The
result of an attempt to exercise the
identified potential authority thus
would appear, at best, to result in a
patchwork framework that appears
unlikely to materially address many of
the concerns historically raised to
justify conduct rules while being likely
to introduce regulatory distortions in
the marketplace.
267. Authority over ISPs That Also
Offer Telecommunications Services. On
this record, claims of authority to adopt
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
7906
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
conduct rules governing ISPs that also
offer telecommunications services have
many shortcomings. The Open Internet
Order contended that ISPs that also offer
telecommunications services might
engage in network management
practices or prioritization that reduces
competition for their voice services,
arguably implicating Section 201(b)’s
prohibition on unjust or unreasonable
rates or practices in the case of common
carrier voice services and/or Section
251(a)(1)’s interconnection requirements
for common carriers. The Open Internet
Order never squares these legal theories
with the statutory prohibition on
treating telecommunications carriers as
common carriers when they are not
engaged in the provision of
telecommunications service or with the
similar restriction on common carrier
treatment of private mobile services.
That Order also is ambiguous whether it
is relying on these provisions for direct
or ancillary authority. If claiming direct
authority, the Open Internet Order fails
to reconcile its theories with relevant
precedent and to address key factual
questions. With respect to Section 201,
in the Computer Inquiries, for example,
when the Commission concluded that
facilities-based carriers’ actions when
offering enhanced services might affect
the justness and reasonableness of their
common carrier offerings under Section
201, it responded by exercising ancillary
authority, rather than direct authority
under Section 201. With respect to
Section 251(a)(1), the Commission has
held that that provision only involves
the linking of networks and not the
transport and termination of traffic. The
Open Internet Order does not explain
why telecommunications carriers would
seek to link their networks with other
carriers by delivering traffic through a
broadband internet access service rather
than through normal means of direct or
indirect interconnection. Even in the
more likely case that these represented
theories of ancillary authority, the Open
Internet Order’s failure to forthrightly
engage with the theories on those terms
leaves it unclear how conduct rules are
sufficiently ‘‘necessary’’ to the
implementation of Section 201 and/or
Section 251(a)(1) to satisfy the standard
for ancillary authority under Comcast.
The limited, indirect references to
Section 201 and 251(a)(1) authority in
the record here do not resolve these
questions about possible Section 201- or
251(a)(1)-based theories, either.
268. The Open Internet Order also
noted that Section 256 of the Act
addresses coordinated network planning
related to interconnection, but did not
put forward a theory for relying on that
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
as authority for conduct rule. To the
contrary, it cited the holding in Comcast
‘‘acknowledging Section 256’s objective,
while adding that Section 256 does not
‘expand[ ] . . . any authority that the
Commission[ ] otherwise has under
law.’ ’’ To the extent that commenters
here mention Section 256 at all, they do
not explain how the Commission could
overcome that holding in Comcast for
purposes of relying on that provision as
authority for rules here.
269. An alarm company urges us to
rely on Section 275 of the Act, but we
see substantial shortcomings in using as
a basis for ancillary authority for
conduct rules. Section 275 of the Act
imposes certain nondiscrimination
requirements on incumbent LECs
related to alarm monitoring services,
along with restrictions on all LECs’
recording or use of data from calls to
alarm monitoring providers for purposes
of marketing competing alarm
monitoring services. Arguments that
ancillary authority based on Section 275
could support rules that prohibit ISPs
that also offer alarm monitoring services
from blocking or throttling alarm
monitoring traffic or engaging in
anticompetitive paid prioritization of
alarm monitoring traffic are premised on
a reading of Section 275 as a far broader
mandate to protecting alarm monitoring
competition than the specifics of its
language support. Given the
Commission’s existing ability to directly
apply the duties and restrictions of
Section 275 to the specific entities
covered by that Section, the record
leaves us unable to conclude that the
proposed alarm monitoring-related ISP
conduct rules are sufficiently
‘‘necessary’’ to our implementation of
Section 275 to satisfy the standard for
ancillary authority under Comcast. Nor
does the record demonstrate what basis
we have for the proposed exercise of
ancillary authority to regulate any ISPs
that fall outside the scope of Section 275
but that offer alarm monitoring services.
270. Authority With Respect to Audio
and Video. The Open Internet Order’s
theories of authority related to
Commission oversight of audio and
video offerings have significant
deficiencies, as well. In that Order, the
Commission argued that because local
television stations and radio stations
distributed their content over the
internet, actions by ISPs to block,
degrade, or charge unreasonable fees for
carrying such traffic would interfere
with certain statutory responsibilities.
Once again, the Commission was
unclear whether it was asserting direct
or ancillary authority. The Open
Internet Order cited policy
pronouncements from provisions of the
PO 00000
Frm 00056
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
Act and associated precedent without
any clear indication how the underlying
authority directly applied to ISPs’
conduct. To the extent that the Open
Internet Order was claiming ancillary
authority, its failure to forthrightly
engage with an ancillary authority
theory again leaves it unclear how
conduct rules are sufficiently
‘‘necessary’’ to its implementation of
these provisions to satisfy the standard
for ancillary authority under Comcast,
nor are these issues adequately
addressed by the limited references to
this potential authority in the record.
271. We find significant limitations to
the Open Internet Order’s theories based
on direct authority under Title VI of the
Act, as well. The Commission
contended in the Open Internet Order
that ‘‘MVPD practices that
discriminatorily impede’’ competing
online video are a ‘‘related practice’’ to
video program carriage agreements and
thus subject to the restrictions in
Section 616(a) of the Act. That
expansive view of a ‘‘related practice’’
seems challenging to square with the
overall structure and approach of
Section 616, which is focused on
facilitating program carriage agreements
between video programming vendors
and MVPDs. But the Open Internet
Order suggests that an MVPD/ISP could
violate rules implementing Section
616(a) with respect to the programming
of a video programming vendor that
never even sought a program carriage
agreement with that MVPD. In such
cases, there appears to be no actual or
potential program carriage agreement to
which the MVPD/ISP’s conduct would
be a ‘‘related practice[ ].’’ To the
contrary, the broader structure of
Section 616(a) seems to contemplate
that there would be some effort by the
video programming vendor to obtain
carriage, subject to the possibly of a
complaint. Neither the Open Internet
Order nor the record here provides a
response enabling us to address these
concerns.
272. The Open Internet Order’s legal
theory under Section 628 of the Act also
appears to have substantial
shortcomings. The Open Internet Order
contended that ‘‘[a] cable or telephone
company’s interference with online
transmission of programming by DBS
operators or stand-alone online video
programming aggregators that may
function as competitive alternatives to
traditional MVPDs would frustrate
Congress’s stated goals in enacting
Section 628 of the Act’’ and ‘‘[t]he
Commission therefore is authorized to
adopt open internet rules under Section
628(b), (c)(1), and (j).’’ Under the terms
of the statute, that at most could restrict
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
such entities’ conduct if it constitutes
‘‘unfair or deceptive acts or practices the
purpose or effect of which is to prevent
or hinder significantly the ability of an
MVPD to deliver satellite cable
programming or satellite broadcast
programming.’’ The cursory discussion
in the Open Internet Order, while
suggesting that ISP practices could have
some effect on the viability of standalone MVPDs like DISH, does not
provide any meaningful explanation
why particular conduct would rise to
the level of ‘‘prevent[ing] or
significantly hinder[ing]’’ DISH (or
others) from being able to deliver
satellite cable programming or satellite
broadcast programming. The minimal
discussion of this Title VI authority in
the record here does not remedy that
shortcoming either.
273. Authority With Respect to
Wireless Licensees. Although the
Commission could rely on Title III
licensing authority to support conduct
rules as it has in the past, that historical
approach would result in disparate
treatment of ISPs, enabling conduct
rules encompassing wireless ISPs, but
not wireline ISPs. For the reasons set
forth below, we decline to adopt a
patchwork of rules that subjects
different categories of ISPs to different
treatment. In addition, applying conduct
rules just to such providers would have
the anomalous result of more heavily
regulating providers that face among the
most competitive marketplace
conditions.
d. Our Evaluation of Possible Authority
for Conduct Rules Confirms That Such
Rules Are Inappropriate
274. Our analyses of potential theories
of legal authority for conduct rules
(other than Title II authority relied upon
in the Title II Order) persuades us on the
record here that ISP conduct rules are
unwarranted. The two provisions most
directly on point—Section 706 of the
1996 Act and Section 230(b) of the
Communications Act—are better read as
policy pronouncements rather than
grants of regulatory authority. In
addition, Section 230(b)(2) identifies
Congress’ deregulatory policy for the
internet, explaining that ‘‘[i]t is the
policy of the United States . . . to
preserve the vibrant and competitive
free market that presently exists for the
internet and other interactive computer
services, unfettered by Federal or State
regulation.’’ This policy is reinforced by
the deregulatory objectives of the 1996
Act more generally. Against that policy
backdrop, had Congress wanted us to
regulate ISPs’ conduct we find it most
likely that they would have spoken to
that directly. Thus, the fact that the
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
Commission would be left here to comb
through myriad provisions of the Act in
an effort to cobble together authority for
ISP conduct rules itself leaves us
dubious such rules really are within the
authority granted by Congress. Because
we decline to adopt conduct rules here,
we need not reach the arguments in the
record that imposing such rules on ISPs
would violate the First Amendment. We
are unpersuaded by the suggestion that
allowing ISPs to enter paid
prioritization arrangements, even if
subject to a commercial reasonableness
standard, would trigger First
Amendment scrutiny as a restriction on
entities wishing to transmit speech on
the internet. The failure to restrict ISPs’
actions through conduct rules does not
require ISPs to act in any particular
manner, and those arguments do not
reveal why allowing ISPs to decide
whether and when to enter paid
prioritization arrangements would
constitute state action triggering the
First Amendment.
275. In addition, the absence of
demonstrated statutory authority that
could support comprehensive conduct
rules would leave us with, at most, a
patchwork of non-uniform rules that
would have problematic consequences
and doubtful value. Virtually all of the
remaining sources of possible authority
identified in the Open Internet Order or
the record here would encompass only
discrete subsets of ISPs, such as ISPs
that otherwise are providing common
carrier voice services; ISPs that
otherwise are cable operators or MVPDs;
or ISPs that hold wireless licenses,
among others. Individually, each of
these sources of authority would leave
substantial segments of ISPs
unaddressed by any conduct rules. In
addition, most of the remaining sources
of authority would, at most, enable the
Commission to target narrow types of
behaviors, including, among other
examples, actions by ISPs that otherwise
offer common carrier voice services to
interfere with competing over-the-top
voice services or actions by certain ISPs
that otherwise are video providers that
harm the distribution of satellite
programming. Importantly, substantial
questions also remain on the record here
about the merits of most of those
theories of legal authority. For example,
most if not all wired ISPs would appear
to fall outside the scope of any sound
basis of authority for conduct rules
addressing the theories of harm
identified in the Open Internet Order.
This would leave substantial portions of
the marketplace unaddressed by
conduct rules including a number of the
largest ISPs.
PO 00000
Frm 00057
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
7907
276. Imposing conduct rules on only
some, but not all, ISPs risks introducing
regulation-based market distortions by
limiting some ISPs’ ability to participate
in the marketplace in a manner
equivalent to other ISPs. ISPs subject to
conduct rules would be limited in the
ways in which they could manage traffic
on their networks and/or the
commercial arrangements they could
enter related to their carriage of traffic
beyond the requirements to which other
ISPs are subject. As a result, they are
likely to face increased network costs
and network management challenges
and see decreased revenue
opportunities from commercial
arrangements relative to existing or
potential competitors not similarly
constrained by conduct rules. In various
contexts, the Commission previously
has recognized that such artificial
regulatory distinctions can distort the
marketplace and undercut competition.
The primary objectives of the 1996 Act
are ‘‘[t]o promote competition and
reduce regulation,’’ and the Commission
likewise has observed that
‘‘[c]ompetitive markets are superior
mechanisms for protecting consumers
by ensuring that goods and services are
provided to consumers in the most
efficient manner possible and at prices
that reflect the cost of production.’’
Thus, the risk that disparate regulatory
treatment under patchwork conduct
rules could harm existing or potential
competition is a significant concern.
Even assuming arguendo that the record
demonstrated harms for which conduct
rules were warranted—which it does
not—the record does not demonstrate
that any incremental benefits from
patchwork regulation would outweigh
the harm from the resulting potential for
marketplace distortions.
277. Patchwork conduct rules also
would not appear to address many of
the theories of harm identified in the
Open Internet Order. A number of those
theories of harm would need to be
addressed by comprehensive or nearcomprehensive conduct rules. Here, by
contrast, substantial segments of the
marketplace would be left unaddressed
by patchwork ISP conduct rules. Thus,
patchwork conduct rules that
conceivably might be supported by
authority identified here would not
meaningfully address such concerns,
even assuming arguendo that the record
here supported such theories of harm.
C. Enforcement
278. In light of the modifications to
our regulations, we also revise our
enforcement practices under them. The
Internet Freedom NPRM sought
comment on the Commission’s
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
7908
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
Ombudsperson, formal complaint rules,
and advisory opinions established in the
Title II Order. For the reasons discussed
below, we remove these enforcement
mechanisms. Our existing informal
complaint procedures combined with
transparency and competition, as well
as antitrust and consumer protection
laws, will ensure that ISPs continue to
be held accountable for their actions,
while removing unnecessary and
ineffective regulatory processes and
unused mechanisms.
279. Open Internet Ombudsperson.
We find that there is no need for a
separate Ombudsperson and thereby
eliminate the Ombudsperson position.
The Title II Order created the role of an
Ombudsperson ‘‘to provide assistance to
individuals and organizations with
questions or complaints regarding the
open internet to ensure that small and
often unrepresented groups reach the
appropriate bureaus and offices to
address specific issues.’’ In particular,
the Title II Order tasked the
Ombudsperson with ‘‘conducting trend
analysis of open internet complaints
and, more broadly, market conditions,
that could be summarized in reports to
the Commission regarding how the
market is functioning for various
stakeholders . . . . [and] investigat[ing]
and bring[ing] attention to open internet
concerns, and refer[ing] matters to the
Enforcement Bureau for potential
further investigation.’’ We agree that it
is important for the Commission to have
staff who monitor consumer complaints
and provide consumers with additional
information; however, we disagree that
a separate Ombudsperson role is
necessary to perform this function
specifically for transparency
complaints. Instead, as suggested in the
record, we determine that the existing
consumer complaint process
administered by the Commission’s
Consumer and Governmental Affairs
Bureau is best suited to and will process
all informal transparency complaints.
We reject as unsupported any
suggestions that only an Ombudsperson,
and not other professional staff from the
Consumer and Governmental Affairs
Bureau, would be able to engage with
consumers in beneficial ways. Indeed,
the name, purpose, and well-established
track record for that Bureau make clear
its understanding of and responsiveness
to consumer concerns.
280. We find that staff from the
Consumer and Governmental Affairs
Bureau—other than the
Ombudsperson—have been performing
the Ombudsperson functions envisioned
by the Title II Order. Since the existing
rules became effective in June 2015, the
Consumer and Governmental Affairs
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
Bureau has engaged in an ongoing
review of informal consumer complaints
submitted to the Ombudsperson and to
the Commission’s Consumer Complaint
Center. Many complaints convey
frustration or dissatisfaction with a
person or entity or discuss a subject
without actually alleging wrongdoing on
which the Commission may act; others
represent isolated incidents that do not
form a trend that allow judicious use of
our limited resources. Staff from the
Consumer and Governmental Affairs
Bureau review all informal open
internet complaints received by the
Commission, and work with staff in the
Enforcement Bureau who also monitor
media reports and conduct additional
research to identify complaint trends so
the Commission can best target its
enforcement capabilities toward entities
that have a pattern of violating the
Communications Act and the
Commission’s rules, regulations, and
orders. The Commission’s decision not
to expend its limited resources
investigating each complaint that
consumers believe may be related to the
open internet rules does not mean that
the Commission ‘‘has not taken the time
to analyze these materials’’ as alleged by
some parties in the record. Rather, this
ongoing review has helped identify
trends in this subject matter as well as
the many others over which we have
jurisdiction and which generate far
more consumer complaints.
281. We emphasize that we are not
making any changes to our informal
complaint processes. Our decision to
eliminate the Open Internet
Ombudsperson does not impact the
existing review of trends or existing
responses to consumer complaints by
the Consumer and Governmental Affairs
Bureau and the Enforcement Bureau.
Instead, it reduces confusion by making
clear that staff specifically trained to
work with consumers, known as
Consumer Advocacy and Mediation
Specialists (CAMS), are best suited to
help consumers by providing them with
understandable information about the
issue they might be experiencing and to
help file a complaint against a service
provider if the consumer believes the
service provider is violating our rules.
When a consumer needs additional
information that the CAMS cannot
provide, that complaint is often shared
with the expert Bureau or Office to
provide additional information to the
consumer.
282. Our experience also persuades us
that the demand for a distinct
Ombudsperson is not sufficient to retain
the position. For the 10 month period
from December 16, 2016 through
November 16, 2017, the email address
PO 00000
Frm 00058
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
and phone number associated with the
Ombudsperson received only 38 emails
and 10 calls related to the open
internet—with only 7 emails and 2 calls
coming in during the 5 month period
between mid-July and mid November
2017. By comparison, during that same
time period, the Consumer and
Governmental Affairs Bureau’s
Consumer Complaint Center received
roughly 7,700 complaints that
consumers identified as relating to open
internet. This figure includes
complaints filed through the Consumer
Complaint Center and the FCC Call
Center for which the consumer selfselected the issue ‘‘Open Internet/Net
Neutrality’’ or the call center agent
selected ‘‘Open Internet’’ based on the
consumer’s description of the issue, and
does not exclude open internet
campaigns. These statistics make clear
that consumers have generally not been
seeking out the Ombudsperson position
for assistance with concerns about
internet openness and that consumers
are comfortable working with the
Consumer and Governmental Affairs
Bureau to protect their interests.
283. Formal Complaint Rules. We
similarly find that it is no longer
necessary to allow for formal complaints
under Part 8 of the Act as we believe
that the informal complaint process is
sufficient in this area. We encourage
consumers to file informal complaints
for apparent violations of the
transparency rule in order to assist the
Commission in monitoring the
broadband market and furthering our
goals under Section 257 to identify
market entry barriers. We also note that
under the revised regulatory approach
adopted today, consumers and other
entities potentially impacted by ISPs’
conduct will have other remedies
available to them outside of the
Commission under other consumer
protection laws to enforce the promises
made under the transparency rule.
284. Advisory Opinions. Because we
are eliminating the conduct rules, we
find that the justification for
enforcement advisory opinions no
longer exists. Moreover, our experience
with enforcement advisory opinions and
the evidence in the record would lead
us to eliminate the use of advisory
opinions in the context of open internet
conduct in any event. The record
indicates that enforcement advisory
opinions do not diminish regulatory
uncertainty, particularly for small
providers. Rather they add costs and
uncertain timelines since there is no
specific timeframe within which to act,
which can also inhibit innovation.
Further, the fact that no ISP has
requested an advisory opinion since
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
they first became available further
demonstrates that they are not needed.
III. Cost-Benefit Analysis
285. The Internet Freedom NPRM
solicited input for a cost-benefit analysis
in this proceeding, with special
emphasis on identifying ‘‘whether the
decision will have positive net
benefits.’’ There was generally favorable
record support for conducting this
analysis. Relying on the findings
discussed above in light of the record
before us and as a result of our
economic analysis, we use a cost-benefit
analysis framework to evaluate key
decisions. While the record provides
little data that would allow us to
quantify the magnitudes of many of the
effects, our findings with respect to the
key decisions we make in this Order
allow for a reasonable assessment of the
direction of the effect on economic
efficiency (i.e. net positive or net
negative benefits). This assessment is
equivalent to conducting a qualitative
cost-benefit analysis, because the
purpose of comparing benefits and costs
is to identify whether a policy change
improves economic efficiency. We reject
the argument that the Internet Freedom
NPRM provided inadequate notice
regarding our cost-benefit analysis here.
The Commission made clear in that
NPRM that it ‘‘propose[d] to compare
the costs and the benefits’’ of each of the
‘‘changes for which we seek comment
above.’’ It also provided detailed
guidance to commenting parties about
the way in which the Commission
proposed to conduct its cost-benefit
analysis, and the nature of the
information it was seeking in order to
do so. The result is a robust record on
we have based our analysis. Moreover,
that NPRM plainly provided ‘‘the terms
or substance of the proposed rule,’’ and
also provided ‘‘sufficient factual detail
and rationale for the rule to permit
interested parties to comment
meaningfully.’’ Nor can there be any
question that ‘‘[t]he final rule’’ is a
‘‘logical outgrowth’’ of the notice.
286. As proposed in the Internet
Freedom NPRM, we evaluate
maintaining the classification of
broadband internet access service as a
telecommunications service (i.e., Title II
regulation); maintaining the internet
conduct rule; maintaining the noblocking rule; maintaining the nothrottling rule; and maintaining the ban
on paid prioritization. Throughout this
section, when discussing maintaining
broadband internet access service as a
telecommunications service, we mean
as implemented by the Title II Order,
where the Commission forbore from
applying some sections of the Act and
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
some Commission rules. We also
evaluate the benefits and costs
associated with transparency
regulations. We make each of these
evaluations by organizing the relevant
economic findings made throughout the
Order into a cost-benefit framework.
287. The primary benefits, costs, and
transfers attributable to this Order are
the changes in the economic welfare of
consumers, ISPs, and edge providers
that would occur due to our actions. In
our analysis of the net benefits of
maintaining the Title II classification,
the internet conduct rule, and the
bright-line rules, we compare against a
state we would expect to exist if we did
not maintain the classification or a
particular rule. As explained in the
Internet Freedom NPRM, we ‘‘recognize
that in certain cases repealing or
eliminating a rule does not result in a
total lack of regulation but instead
means that other regulations continue to
operate or other regulatory bodies will
have authority.’’ As discussed elsewhere
in this Order, when analyzing the net
benefits of maintaining the Title II
classification, our comparison is to a
situation where a Title I regime for
broadband internet access service, and
antitrust and consumer protection
enforcement, remain in place. Further,
given this Order’s adoption of a
transparency rule, when considering net
benefits of the current rules we compare
against a state where the transparency
rule we adopt is in effect (as well as the
antitrust and consumer protection
enforcement that exists under a Title I
classification). We also recognize that
the actions we analyze separately could
potentially be interdependent, but we
believe a separate consideration of each
is a reasonable way to approximate the
net benefits. We believe that attempting
to assert the nature of these
interdependencies, particularly given
the limited record on such matters,
would introduce considerable
subjectivity while not likely improving
the ability of the analysis to guide our
decisions. Moreover, we consider
additional regulation, for example,
adding an additional rule to a baseline
package of Title II regulation and
another rule (or none) is likely to have
greater negative impacts in terms of
regulatory uncertainty, and distortion of
efficient choices, than the baseline
package, while at best having little or no
additional impact on the positive
impacts (if any) of each element of the
baseline package. That is, the
interactions increase uncertainty and
the unintended side effects of each
element, without making each element
materially more effective.
PO 00000
Frm 00059
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
7909
288. To conduct the cost-benefit
analysis, we first consider the question
of maintaining the Title II classification
of broadband internet access service. We
next consider approaches to
transparency. Then to evaluate the
internet conduct rule and the bright-line
rules, we assume that we will not
maintain the Title II classification and
we will adopt our transparency rule.
This approach allows us practically to
evaluate the rules in a way that
incorporates the decisions on
classification and transparency that we
have come to in this Order.
289. Maintaining Title II
Classification of Broadband Internet
Access Service. We have found that the
Title II Order decreased investment and
is likely to continue to decrease
investment by ISPs. These decreases in
investments are likely to result in less
deployment of service to unserved areas
and less upgrading of facilities in
already served areas. For consumers,
this means some will likely not have
access to high-speed services over fixed
or mobile networks and some will not
experience better service as quickly as
they otherwise would under a Title I
classification. While the evidence in the
record on the effect of Title II is varied
in terms of details due to different
methodologies, data, etc., we found that
the Title II classification did
directionally decrease investment by
ISPs. Since the Title II Order classified
broadband internet access service under
Title II and adopted rules
simultaneously, it is difficult
methodologically to make a clear
delineation between the effect of the
classification and the rules. However,
the theoretical underpinnings of our
finding about the effect of Title II
specifically also support the finding of
a negative impact on investment as a
result of Title II per se.
290. As the Internet Freedom NPRM
noted, ‘‘the networks built with capital
investments are only a means to an end
. . . the private costs borne by
consumers and businesses of
maintaining the status quo [i.e., Title II
classification] result from decreased
value derived from using the networks.’’
Ideally, we would estimate consumers’
and businesses’ valuations of the service
or service improvements foregone
caused by Title II classification.
Unfortunately, the record before us does
not allow for such estimation. We can
reasonably conclude, however, that
providers expect to recoup their
investments over time through revenues
generated by employing the networks
resulting from the investment. Since
these revenues come from consumers
and businesses who are willing to pay
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
7910
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
at least their value of the service, the
investment foregone due to Title II is a
lower bound on the value consumers
lose if the FCC maintains the Title II
classification. This is a conservative
estimate as the social welfare impact of
this forgone investment would likely
have been positive, because frequently
(1) a customer’s willingness to pay
exceeds what the customer actually
pays, and (2) the provider may make an
economic profit. We therefore conclude
that the private costs of maintaining a
Title II classification due to foregone
network investment are directionally
negative and likely constitute at least
several billion dollars annually based on
the record.
291. The Commission also asked in
the Internet Freedom NPRM about
additional costs that could result from
foregone network investments. When
regulation discourages investment in the
network, society is likely to lose some
spillover benefits that the purchasers of
broadband internet access do not
themselves capture. Such forgone
benefits can include network
externalities (the network becomes more
valuable the more users are on the
network, but individual ISPs do not
capture all of these, as they are obtained
by end users on other ISPs’ networks),
and improvements in productivity and
innovation that occur because
broadband is a general-purpose
technology. The record provides little
information that could be used to
quantify such costs, but it is reasonable
to conclude that there are social costs
beyond the private costs associated with
the foregone investment.
292. Next, we consider the benefits
associated with maintaining the Title II
classification. The relevant comparison
is what incremental benefit the Title II
classification provides over and above
the Title I scenario. In the Title I
scenario, the FTC has jurisdiction over
broadband internet access service
providers. The record does not convince
us that Title II classification per se
provides any benefit over and above
Title I classification. We also find above
that the record does not provide
evidence supporting the conclusion that
the Title II classification affects edge
investment. To the extent Title II
provides a benefit, it appears to do so
by serving as a legal basis relied upon
to adopt rules. Therefore, in this costbenefit analysis we conclude the
incremental benefits of maintaining the
Title II classification are approximately
zero.
293. Finding that the benefits of
maintaining the Title II classification are
approximately zero, coupled with our
finding that the private and social costs
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
are positive, we conclude that
maintaining the Title II classification
would have net negative benefits. Thus,
maintaining the Title II classification
would decrease overall economic
welfare, and our cost-benefit analysis
supports the decision to reclassify
broadband internet access service as a
Title I service.
294. Evaluating Transparency Rules.
As discussed already, we find that the
benefits of a transparency rule are
positive based on the record. Given our
decision to classify broadband internet
access service under Title I, the benefits
of a transparency rule are expected to be
of considerable magnitude since it is a
key element of our approach of relying
on enforcement under antitrust and
consumer protection law to prevent and
remedy harmful behaviors by ISPs.
Numerous commenters indicate the
benefits of a free and open internet are
large, so to the extent a transparency
rule under our Title I approach is
important for maintaining a free and
open internet, we can conclude the
benefits are positive and considerable.
Furthermore, transparency can provide
other benefits in terms of consumer
welfare. Namely, if transparency helps
mitigate economic deadweight loss due
to information asymmetry or if it helps
consumers better satisfy their
preferences in their purchasing
decisions, then additional benefits will
accrue. We therefore conclude that our
transparency approach, as well as the
transparency approaches in the Open
Internet Order and the Title II Order, all
have positive benefits.
295. The costs of the transparency
rules may vary given differences in their
implementation. Comparing the
transparency approach in the Open
Internet Order and the Title II Order, we
conclude the costs were greater for the
latter. Based on the record, we
determined above that the additional
transparency requirements in the Title II
Order were particularly burdensome.
Although the record is limited on the
costs of these transparency rules, the
Commission’s Paperwork Reduction Act
(PRA) filings indicate the Title II Order
transparency rule increased the burden
on the public by thousands of hours per
year, costing hundreds of thousands of
dollars. While we do not have specific
information on our transparency rule’s
costs, it is fairly similar to that in the
Open Internet Order. Therefore, we
conclude that a reasonable
approximation for the PRA burden
associated with our rule is
approximately half the preceding
burden estimate. We recognize there are
other costs to this requirement not
accounted for in the PRA estimate,
PO 00000
Frm 00060
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
though the PRA estimate provides a
starting point for sizing the costs,
particularly as we compare several
alternative transparency approaches.
296. Combining our conclusion about
the benefits of a transparency rule with
our assessments of the costs of the
several transparency rules, we conclude
that the transparency rule in the Title II
Order would have the smallest net
positive benefit of the three. That is
because we do not believe the
additional elements of the Title II Order
transparency regime have significant
additional benefits but they do impose
significant additional costs. However,
our transparency rule would have a
larger net positive benefit than the
transparency rule in the Title II Order.
Therefore, our cost-benefit analysis of
the transparency alternatives supports
our decision to adopt a transparency
rule more limited than the one in the
Title II Order.
297. Maintaining the Internet Conduct
Rule. We have determined elsewhere
that the internet conduct rule has
created uncertainty and ultimately
deterred innovation and investment.
The record does not provide sufficient
information for us to estimate the
magnitude of this effect. However, we
do find that maintaining the internet
conduct rule imposes social costs in
terms of increased uncertainty, reduced
investment, and reduced innovation.
298. We also find above that the
benefits of the internet conduct standard
are limited if not approximately zero. In
this cost-benefit analysis, we consider
the incremental benefit of the internet
conduct standard relative to the
regulatory environment created by this
Order. The regulatory environment
created by this Order will have antitrust
and consumer protection enforcement
in place through the FTC. We find that
the internet conduct standard provides
approximately zero additional benefits
compared to that baseline.
299. Based on the record available, we
conclude that maintaining the internet
conduct standard would impose net
negative benefits. The costs of the rule
are considerable as the evidence shows
that it had large effects on consumers
obtaining innovative services (as
demonstrated by the zero-rating
experiences). The innovations that were
delayed or never brought to market
would likely have cost many millions or
even billions of dollars in lost consumer
welfare. At the same time, for the
reasons explained already, the benefits
of the conduct rule are approximately
zero. This leads us to conclude that the
internet conduct standard has a net
negative effect on economic welfare,
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
and supports our decision not to
maintain the internet conduct rule.
300. Maintaining the Ban on Paid
Prioritization. We have determined
elsewhere in this Order that the ban on
paid prioritization has created
uncertainty and reduced ISP
investment. We also find that the ban is
likely to prevent certain types of
innovative applications from being
developed or adopted. The record does
not provide sufficient information for us
to estimate the magnitude of these
effects. However, we do find that
maintaining the ban on paid
prioritization imposes substantial social
costs.
301. We also find above that the
benefits of the ban on paid prioritization
are limited. In this cost-benefit analysis,
we consider the incremental benefit of
the ban on paid prioritization relative to
the regulatory environment created by
this Order. The regulatory environment
created by this Order will have antitrust
and consumer protection enforcement
in place. So we must ask what the ban
on paid prioritization provides in
additional benefits when compared to
that baseline. We concluded that
transparency combined with antitrust
and consumer enforcement at the FTC
will be able to address the vast majority
of harms the ban on paid prioritization
is intended to prevent. To the extent
there are harms not well addressed by
this enforcement, we would expect
those cases to be infrequent and involve
relatively small amounts of harm,
though the record does not allow us to
estimate this magnitude. Antitrust law,
in combination with the transparency
rule we adopt, is particularly wellsuited to addressing any potential or
actual anticompetitive harms that may
arise from paid prioritization
arrangements. While antitrust law does
not address harms that may arise from
the legal use of market power, we have
found that such market power is
limited, and ISPs also have
countervailing incentives to keep edge
provider output high and keep
subscribers on the network. The record
therefore supports a finding of small to
zero benefits.
302. Based on the record available, we
conclude that maintaining the ban on
paid prioritization would impose net
negative benefits. The record shows that
in some cases innovative services and
business models would benefit from
paid prioritization. At the same time, for
the reasons explained already, the
benefits of maintaining the ban are
small or zero. We therefore conclude
that the ban on paid prioritization has
a net negative effect on economic
welfare. This conclusion supports our
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
decision to not maintain the ban on paid
prioritization.
303. Maintaining the Bans on
Blocking and Throttling. We find that
the costs of these bans are likely small.
This is supported by the fact that ISPs
voluntarily have chosen in some cases
to commit to not blocking or throttling.
However, we also recognize that these
rules may create some compliance costs
nonetheless. For example, when
considering new approaches to
managing network traffic, an ISP must
apply due diligence in evaluating
whether the practice might be perceived
as running afoul of the rules. As
network management becomes
increasingly complex, the compliance
costs of these rules could increase.
304. Having adopted a transparency
rule, we find the benefits of bans on
blocking and throttling are
approximately zero since the
transparency rule will allow antitrust
and consumer protection law, coupled
with consumer expectations and ISP
incentives, to mitigate potential harms.
That is, we have determined that
replacing the prohibitions on blocking
and throttling with a transparency rule
implements a lower-cost method of
ensuring that threats to internet
openness are exposed and deterred by
market forces, public opprobrium, and
enforcement of the consumer protection
laws. We conclude therefore that
maintaining the bans on blocking and
throttling has a small net negative
benefit, compared to the new regulatory
environment we create (i.e. Title I
classification and our transparency
rule).
IV. Order
A. Denial of INCOMPAS Petition To
Modify Protective Orders
305. INCOMPAS requests that we
modify the protective orders in four
recent major transaction proceedings
involving internet service providers to
allow confidential materials submitted
in those dockets to be used in this
proceeding. INCOMPAS argues that the
materials ‘‘are necessary to
understanding and fully analyzing
incumbent broadband providers’ ability
and incentives to harm edge providers.’’
The motion is opposed by the three
companies whose materials would be
most affected—Comcast, Charter and
AT&T—as well as by Verizon. For the
reasons set forth below, after carefully
‘‘balancing . . . the public and private
interests involved,’’ we deny
INCOMPAS’s request.
306. The Commission’s protective
orders limit parties’ use of the materials
obtained under the protective order
PO 00000
Frm 00061
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
7911
solely to ‘‘the preparation and conduct’’
of that particular proceeding, and
expressly prohibit the materials being
used ‘‘for any other purpose, including
. . . in any other administrative,
regulatory or judicial proceedings.’’ The
terms of the relevant protective orders
therefore prohibit INCOMPAS from
using the confidential materials it
obtained in those prior dockets in the
current proceeding. Further, parties
reasonably expect that the information
they submit pursuant to the strictures of
a protective order will be used in
accordance with the terms of that order
and that the order’s explicit prohibitions
will not be changed years later. That is
not to imply, however, that the
Commission cannot request the
submission of information in a
proceeding simply because it has been
provided pursuant to a protective order
in another proceeding.
307. Before discussing the substance
of INCOMPAS’s request, we note that,
as a formal matter, the Commission does
not modify protective orders to allow
materials to be used in a different
proceeding. Rather, where we find that
the public interest is served by
submitting certain materials into a
docket, we do so, subject to a protective
order specific to that proceeding if the
material is confidential. That is true
whether the materials have been
submitted in prior proceedings or not.
The question before us, then, is whether
we will require the relevant parties to
submit into this docket the
presumptively confidential information
INCOMPAS has identified.
308. The Commission is not required
to enter into the record and review
every document that a party to a
proceeding deems relevant, especially
where, as here, those documents may
number in the tens of thousands. Nor,
as a general matter, does the
Commission allow for discovery by
parties—which is essentially what
INCOMPAS seeks here—except in
adjudications that have been set for
hearing. The Commission has broad
discretion in how to manage its own
proceedings, and we find several
problems with requiring the materials
INCOMPAS seeks to be submitted into
this rulemaking docket.
309. First, much of the material
INCOMPAS seeks is now several years
old and INCOMPAS has offered little
demonstration of its relevance to this
proceeding. For example, Comcast’s
ability to discriminate against online
video providers in 2009 and 2010 shines
little light on its ability to do so now.
Also, as the opponents argue, many of
the confidential materials cited by the
Commission in its prior transaction
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
7912
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
decisions were cited as part of a larger
group of mostly publicly available
information. Having the competitively
sensitive information from those
transactions in this record would
therefore not significantly add to the
Commission’s understanding of the
issues, especially since the participants
in the current proceeding and the
Commission already have available the
Commission’s prior conclusions and
reasoning, as well as the underlying
public information.
310. Second, INCOMPAS asks for
information only from the few industry
participants who happen to have had
large transactions before the
Commission. But where the
Commission has sought information in
large rulemaking proceedings, it sought
information from the entire industry,
not just from a select few participants.
Transaction review is an adjudicatory
matter, involving the entities engaging
in the transaction—not the entire
industry or marketplace. Particularly
given that there are thousands of ISPs
doing business in the United States,
INCOMPAS does not address how a
quite incomplete picture of industry
practices could meaningfully improve
the Commission’s analysis.
311. Third, granting the request
would pose several administrative
difficulties. It is unclear how much of
the material INCOMPAS seeks is still in
the possession of the parties: The
relevant portions of the proceedings are
finished, and many of the materials may
have been destroyed. And what is
available at the Commission would be
difficult and costly to produce. Making
the information available to others also
would be administratively difficult. For
example, in the recent Business Data
Services proceeding, the Commission
made the competitively sensitive data
available for review only through a
secure data enclave, a process which
took significant time and resources to
establish. And in most Commission
proceedings, the parties who own the
confidential information are required to
provide that material directly to persons
who seek to review it pursuant to terms
outlined in the applicable protective
order. Here, in contrast, it is likely that
the Commission itself would have to
make the confidential information
available, further depleting scarce
Commission resources.
312. Finally, as noted above, the
materials INCOMPAS seeks were
provided pursuant to express assurances
against their use in future proceedings.
313. INCOMPAS cites two examples
in which the Commission staff placed
into the record competitively sensitive
materials originally submitted in
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
another docket. We find both
inapposite. As an initial matter, we note
that the Commission is not bound by its
staff’s prior decisions. The first example
INCOMPAS cites involved a series of
spectrum license transfers between
wireless telecommunications companies
where the Commission added
confidential data to the docket under a
new protective order. When evaluating
transactions such as these, the
Commission regularly uses subscriber
data derived from regular periodic
confidential filings made by all
telecommunications companies to
determine market shares. In such
transactions, this use of subscriber data
is often the only way to calculate market
share, which is a critical element to
analyzing the potential competitive
harms of the proposed transaction.
Balancing that need against the
potential competitive harm to providers,
we have determined that allowing that
material to be reviewed pursuant to a
protective order best serves the public
interest. For the reasons expressed
above, we do not reach the same
conclusions with respect to the
materials here.
314. INCOMPAS also cites the recent
investigation of certain business data
services tariffs, in which the
Commission placed the record of the
contemporaneous business data services
rulemaking proceeding into the docket
of the tariff investigations. As the
opponents note, the tariff investigation
was not only related to the rulemaking
proceeding, it actually was determined
by the staff to be ‘‘an outgrowth’’ of that
proceeding. Further, there was no
Commission decision in the rulemaking
proceeding on which the participants in
the tariff proceeding could rely; the
proceeding was still ongoing. All of the
participants in the tariff proceeding,
moreover, were participating in the
rulemaking proceeding. Here, by
contrast, the current rulemaking is not
related to the prior transactions; the
parties may rely on prior written
Commission decisions; and literally
millions more comments have been
submitted in this rulemaking than in the
prior transaction proceedings. Finally,
we note that none of the parties that
owned the confidential information in
the Business Data Services rulemaking
proceeding raised confidentiality
concerns with respect to that
information being placed into the tariff
investigation docket. Here, they do.
315. Even absent the legal and
administrative barriers discussed above,
the substance of the past transaction
orders compels us to deny INCOMPAS’
motion. When, as it has in the past, the
Commission determines a specific
PO 00000
Frm 00062
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
transaction involving certain large
broadband providers is likely to create
competitive or other public interest
harm, the conditions imposed are
applicable only to those entities
engaging in the transaction. Those
proceedings involved some of the
nation’s largest broadband providers,
and the Commission’s conclusions were
based on the specific circumstances
involved. This is because transaction
review is an adjudicatory matter,
involving the motives, plans, and
capabilities of the entities engaging in
the transaction—not the entire industry
or marketplace. Indeed, transaction
reviews specifically do not address
issues that are not transaction-specific
but are industry-wide. The targeted and
flexible approach the Commission used
to ameliorate the potential harms it
found in those transactions is not
transferable to a permanent, one-sizefits-all approach in this rulemaking
applicable to hundreds of ISPs.
316. Further, in those limited
instances in which the Commission
found conduct remedies necessary, it
almost always applied them on a
temporary basis, in recognition that
markets change over time. That is true
even more so in industries that are
characterized by rapidly changing
technologies. Similarly, the Commission
often has provided that it will ‘‘consider
a petition for modification of this
condition if it can be demonstrated that
there has been a material change in
circumstance or the condition has
proven unduly burdensome, rendering
the condition no longer necessary in the
public interest,’’ and has acted
accordingly. None of this would be the
case with respect to the regulations that
some commenters urge us to adopt in
this rulemaking.
317. INCOMPAS argues that
‘‘[l]ooking to the past is the standard
way for administrative agencies to make
predictive judgments.’’ However, the
analysis supporting our decision to reclassify broadband internet access
service as an information service is
quite different from the analysis the
Commission employs when conducting
a transaction review. In this rulemaking,
we are not considering whether, as a
result of a transfer of a Commission
license, a licensee is likely to gain
market power, allowing it to take
anticompetitive actions that it otherwise
could not. Instead, we are reasonably
considering the long-term costs and
benefits of Title II and other ex ante
regulation in an increasingly dynamic
market. As such, we choose a
conservative and administrable
approach to formulating a light-touch
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
regulatory framework—which is
appropriate in a rulemaking.
318. In addition to rejecting the
INCOMPAS petition on the merits, we
find that the petition is procedurally
flawed. Although some of the
companies that objected to
INCOMPAS’s request were the
applicants in the proceedings from
which INCOMPAS seeks confidential
information, they are not the only
owners of confidential information
submitted in those dockets. INCOMPAS
did not file its request in those
dockets—which are long dormant—and
others whose confidential information
would be disclosed if we were to grant
INCOMPAS’s request have not been
notified of the request to have the
opportunity to object. That would need
to occur before any of their information
could be made available, even pursuant
to a protective order.
319. Taking into account and sensibly
balancing the factors discussed above,
we find that the public interest would
not be served by requiring the
submission into the docket of the
current proceeding the presumptively
confidential information INCOMPAS
seeks. We therefore deny INCOMPAS’s
request.
B. Denial of NHMC Motion Regarding
Informal Consumer Complaints
320. The National Hispanic Media
Coalition (NHMC) requests that we
incorporate in the record of this
proceeding the informal complaint
materials released as part of NHMC’s
Freedom of Information Act (FOIA)
request and establish a new pleading
cycle for public comment on those
materials. NHMC argues that the
materials ‘‘are directly relevant to the
[NPRM’s] questions regarding the
effectiveness of the [Title II Order]’’ and
that if we deny NHMC’s request, ‘‘any
decision in this proceeding would be
based on an insufficient and
fundamentally flawed record.’’ The
motion is opposed by several parties
who argue that the informal complaint
materials are not relevant to this
proceeding, and that the motion
‘‘appears to be . . . aimed [ ] at
prolonging this proceeding
unnecessarily.’’ For the reasons set forth
below, we deny NHMC’s request.
321. In responding to NHMC’s
underlying FOIA requests, we produced
nearly 70,000 pages of records
responsive to the requests. The
documents we provided to NHMC
included informal consumer complaints
filed with the Consumer and
Governmental Affairs Bureau, data
relating to the complaints, responses to
the informal complaints from the carrier
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
involved in a specific complaint—all
filed by the consumer under the
category of Open Internet/Net
Neutrality—and consumer complaint
correspondence with the Open Internet
Ombudsperson. We provided this large
quantity of documents to NHMC on a
rolling basis and made all of the
documents available to the public in our
FOIA Electronic Reading Room.
322. Under Commission rules, and as
noted by opponents to the motion,
‘‘NHMC is free to put into the record
whatever it believes to be relevant via ex
parte letters.’’ NHMC began receiving
the documents it claims are relevant to
the proceeding on June 20, 2017. During
the following months, NHMC engaged
with Commission staff to discuss the
consumer complaint documents. NHMC
also conducted an Expert Analysis of
the consumer complaint documents and
submitted the analysis along with the
complaints it found relevant in the
record, in addition to submitting the full
universe of consumer complaints it
received under the FOIA request into
the record on December 1—nearly three
months after the Commission produced
them all. Thus, we remain unpersuaded
that NHMC requires additional time to
review the documents and instead agree
with commenters that NHMC has raised
‘‘the mere existence of these complaints
as a pretext for delay.’’
323. The Internet Freedom NPRM
sought comment on consumer harm in
a variety of contexts and, in response,
received over 22 million comments
discussing consumers’ view of the Title
II Order, including any harm that may
or may not have occurred under its
rules. After routinely reviewing the
consumer complaints over the past two
years, and conducting a robust review of
the voluminous record in this
proceeding, we agree with opponents to
the motion that ‘‘it is exceedingly
unlikely that these informal complaints
identify any net neutrality ‘problem’
that [advocates] have somehow
overlooked in their many massive
submissions in this docket.’’ The
Commission takes consumer complaints
seriously and finds them valuable in
informing us about trends in the
marketplace, but we reiterate that they
are informal complaints that, in most
instances, have not been verified.
Further, the overwhelming majority of
these informal complaints do not allege
conduct implicating the Open Internet
rules. Of the complaints that do discuss
ISPs, they often allege frustration with
a person or entity, but do not allege
wrongdoing under the Open Internet
rules. The consumer complaints NHMC
submitted in the record as part of the
Expert Analysis further support this
PO 00000
Frm 00063
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
7913
point. Further, we are not required to
resolve all of these informal complaints
before proceeding with a rulemaking.
Since we do not rely on these informal
complaints as the basis for the decisions
we make today, we do not have an
obligation to incorporate them into the
record.
324. We are convinced that we have
a full and complete record on which to
base our determination today without
incorporating the materials requested by
NHMC. Further, because the record
remained open for over three months
after the complete production of
documents under NHMC FOIA’s
request, and NHMC filed an analysis the
materials it deemed relevant in the
record, we believe that NHMC had
ample opportunity to ‘‘meaningfully
review the informal complaint materials
and provide comment.’’
V. Procedural Matters
A. The Administrative Record
325. In reviewing the record in this
rulemaking, the Commission complied
with its obligations under the
Administrative Procedure Act (APA),
including the obligation to consider all
‘‘relevant matter’’ received, to
adequately consider ‘‘important
aspect[s] of the problem,’’ and to
‘‘reasonably respond to those comments
that raise significant problems.’’
Consistent with these obligations, the
Commission focused its review of the
record on the submitted comments that
bear substantively on the legal and
public policy consequences of the
actions we take today. Thus, our
decision to restore internet freedom did
not rely on comments devoid of
substance, or the thousands of identical
or nearly-identical non-substantive
comments that simply convey support
or opposition to the proposals in the
Internet Freedom NPRM.
326. Because we have complied with
our obligations under the APA, we
reject calls to delay adoption of this
Order out of concerns that certain nonsubstantive comments (on which the
Commission did not rely) may have
been submitted under multiple different
names or allegedly ‘‘fake’’ names. The
Commission is under no legal obligation
to adopt any ‘‘procedural devices’’
beyond what the APA requires, such as
identity-verification procedures. In
addition, the Commission has
previously decided not to apply its
internal rules regarding false statements
in the rulemaking context because we
do not want ‘‘to hinder full and robust
public participation in such
policymaking proceedings by
encouraging collateral wrangling over
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
7914
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
gives ISPs flexibility in how to
implement the disclosure rule, (2) the
rule gives providers adequate time to
develop cost-effective methods of
compliance, and (3) the rule eliminates
the additional reporting obligations
adopted in the Title II Order.
B. Final Regulatory Flexibility Analysis
327. As required by the Regulatory
Flexibility Act (RFA), an Initial
Regulatory Flexibility Analysis (IRFA)
was incorporated into the Internet
Freedom NPRM. The Commission
sought written public comment on the
possible significant economic impact on
small entities regarding the proposals
addressed in the Internet Freedom
NPRM, including comments on the
IRFA. Pursuant to the RFA, a Final
Regulatory Flexibility Analysis is set
forth in the Order.
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
the truthfulness of the parties’
statements.’’ To the extent that members
of the public are concerned about the
presence in the record of identical or
nearly-identical non-substantive
comments that simply convey support
or opposition to the proposals in the
Internet Freedom NPRM, those
comments in no way impeded the
Commission’s ability to identify or
respond to material issues in the record.
Indeed, the Order demonstrates the
Commission’s deep engagement with
the substantive legal and public policy
questions presented in this proceeding.
E. Data Quality Act
331. The Commission certifies that it
has complied with the Office of
Management and Budget Final
Information Quality Bulletin for Peer
Review, 70 FR 2664, January 14, 2005,
and the Data Quality Act, Public Law
106–554 (2001), codified at 44 U.S.C.
3516 note, with regard to its reliance on
influential scientific information in the
Declaratory Ruling, Report and Order,
and Order in WC Docket No. 17–108.
C. Paperwork Reduction Act Analysis
328. This document contains new or
modified information collection
requirements subject to the Paperwork
Reduction Act of 1995 (PRA), Public
Law 104–13. It will be submitted to the
Office of Management and Budget
(OMB) for review under Section 3507(d)
of the PRA. OMB, the general public,
and other federal agencies will be
invited to comment on the new
information collection requirements
contained in this proceeding. In
addition, we note that pursuant to the
Small Business Paperwork Relief Act of
2002, Public Law 107–198, see 44 U.S.C.
3506(c)(4), we previously sought
specific comment on how the
Commission might further reduce the
information collection burden for small
business concerns with fewer than 25
employees.
329. In this present document, we
require any person providing broadband
internet access service to publicly
disclose accurate information regarding
the network management practices,
performance, and commercial terms of
their broadband internet access services
sufficient to enable consumers to make
informed choices regarding the
purchase and use of such services and
entrepreneurs and other small
businesses to develop, market, and
maintain internet offerings. We have
assessed the effects of this rule and find
that any burden on small businesses
will be minimal because (1) the rule
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
D. Congressional Review Act
330. The Commission will send a
copy of the Report and Order to
Congress and the Government
Accountability Office pursuant to the
Congressional Review Act, see 5 U.S.C.
801(a)(1)(A).
F. Accessible Formats
332. To request materials in accessible
formats for people with disabilities
(braille, large print, electronic files,
audio format), send an email to fcc504@
fcc.gov or call the Consumer &
Governmental Affairs Bureau at 202–
418–0530 (voice), 202–418–0432 (tty).
Contact the FCC to request reasonable
accommodations for filing comments
(accessible format documents, sign
language interpreters, CARTS, etc.) by
email: FCC504@fcc.gov; phone: (202)
418–0530 (voice), (202) 418–0432
(TTY).
VI. Final Regulatory Flexibility
Analysis
333. As required by the Regulatory
Flexibility Act of 1980 (RFA), as
amended, Initial Regulatory Flexibility
Analysis (IRFAs) was incorporated in
the Notice of Proposed Rule Making
(Internet Freedom NPRM) for this
proceeding. The Commission sought
written public comment on the
proposals in the Internet Freedom
NPRM, including comment on the IRFA.
The Commission received comments on
the Internet Freedom NPRM IRFA,
which are discussed below. This present
Final Regulatory Flexibility Analysis
(FRFA) conforms to the RFA.
A. Need for, and Objectives of, the Final
Rules
334. In order to return the internet to
the light-touch regulatory environment
that allowed investment to increase and
consumers to benefit, we return
PO 00000
Frm 00064
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
broadband internet access service to its
longstanding classification as an
information service, and eliminate
several rules adopted in the Title II
Order, including the general conduct
standard, the ban on paid prioritization,
and the no-blocking and no-throttling
rules. We retain the transparency rule
adopted in the Open Internet Order,
with modifications, while eliminating
the additional reporting obligations
created in the Title II Order, the Title II
Order’s direct notification requirement,
and the broadband label ‘‘safe harbor.’’
335. We also eliminate the formal
complaint procedures under Part 8 of
the Act, because the informal complaint
procedures are sufficient. We eliminate
the other components of the
enforcement regime created in the Title
II Order, including the position of Open
Internet Ombudsperson and the
issuance of advisory opinions. We also
return mobile broadband internet access
service to its longstanding definition as
a private mobile radio service under
Section 332 of the Communications Act.
The transparency rule we adopt is
necessary because properly tailored
transparency disclosures provide
valuable information to the Commission
to enable it to meet its statutory
obligation to observe the
communications marketplace to monitor
the introduction of new services and
technologies, and to identify and
eliminate potential marketplace barriers
for the provision of information service.
Such disclosures also provide valuable
information to other internet ecosystem
participants; transparency substantially
reduces the possibility that ISPs will
engage in harmful practices, and it
incentivizes quick corrective measures
by providers if problematic conduct is
identified. Appropriate disclosures help
consumers make informed choices
about their purchase and use of
broadband services. Moreover, clear
disclosures improve consumer
confidence in ISPs’ practices, ultimately
increasing user adoption and leading to
additional investment and innovation,
while providing entrepreneurs and
other small businesses the necessary
information to innovate and improve
products.
336. Our enforcement changes will
ensure that ISPs will be held
accountable for any violations of the
transparency rule. We eliminate the
formal complaint procedures because
the informal complaint procedure, in
conjunction with other redress options
including consumer protection laws,
will sufficiently protect consumers.
Additionally, we eliminate the position
of Open Internet Ombudsperson
because the staff from the Consumer and
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
Governmental Affairs Bureau—other
than the Ombudsperson—have been
performing the Ombudsperson
functions envisioned by the Title II
Order. We also eliminate the issuance of
enforcement advisory opinions, because
enforcement advisory opinions do not
diminish regulatory uncertainty,
particularly for small providers. Instead,
they add costs and uncertain timelines
since there is no specific timeframe
within which to act, which can also
inhibit innovation.
337. We return mobile broadband
internet access service to its original
classification as a private mobile radio
service because we find that the
definitions of the terms ‘‘public
switched network’’ and ‘‘interconnected
service’’ that the Commission adopted
in the 1994 Second CMRS Report and
Order reflect a better reading of the Act.
Accordingly, we readopt those
definitions.
338. We restore the definition of
interconnected service that existed prior
to the Title II Order. Prior to that Order,
the term ‘‘interconnected service’’ was
defined under the Commission’s rules
as a service ‘‘that gives subscribers the
capability to communicate to or receive
communication from all other users on
the public switched network.’’ The Title
II Order modified this definition by
deleting the word ‘‘all,’’ finding that
mobile broadband internet access
service should still be considered an
interconnected service even if it only
enabled users to communicate with
‘‘some’’ other users of the public
switched network rather than all. We
conclude that the better reading of
‘‘interconnected service’’ is one that
enables communication between its
users and all other users of the public
switched network.
339. The legal basis for the rules we
adopt today includes sections 3, 4,
201(b), 230, 231, 257, 303, 332, 403,
501, and 503 of the Communications
Act of 1934, as amended, 47 U.S.C. 153,
154, 201(b), 230, 231, 257, 303, 332,
403, 501, 503. The transparency rule we
adopt today relies on Section 257 of the
Communications Act. Section 257
requires the Commission to make
triennial reports to Congress, and those
triennial reports must identify ‘‘market
entry barriers for entrepreneurs and
other small businesses in the provision
and ownership of telecommunications
services and information services.’’
B. Summary of Significant Issues Raised
by Public Comments to the IRFA
340. The Wireless Internet Service
Providers Association (WISPA) argued
that the IRFA was incomplete and
inaccurate. We find that this FRFA
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
sufficiently addresses WISPA’s concerns
and explains how we ‘‘alleviate many of
the significant financial harms on small
providers imposed by the [Title II
Order].’’
C. Response to Comments by the Chief
Counsel for Advocacy of the Small
Business Administration
341. Pursuant to the Small Business
Jobs Act of 2010, which amended the
RFA, the Commission is required to
respond to any comments filed by the
Chief Counsel of the Small Business
Administration (SBA), and to provide a
detailed statement of any change made
to the proposed rule(s) as a result of
those comments.
342. The Chief Counsel did not file
any comments in response to the
proposed rule(s) in this proceeding.
D. Description and Estimate of the
Number of Small Entities To Which the
Final Rule May Apply
343. The RFA directs agencies to
provide a description of and, where
feasible, an estimate of the number of
small entities that may be affected by
the proposed rules, if adopted. The RFA
generally defines the term ‘‘small
entity’’ as having the same meaning as
the terms ‘‘small business,’’ ‘‘small
organization,’’ and ‘‘small governmental
jurisdiction.’’ In addition, the term
‘‘small business’’ has the same meaning
as the term ‘‘small business concern’’
under the Small Business Act. A small
business concern is one that: (1) Is
independently owned and operated; (2)
is not dominant in its field of operation;
and (3) satisfies any additional criteria
established by the Small Business
Administration (SBA). Nationwide,
there are a total of approximately 28.2
million small businesses, according to
the SBA. A ‘‘small organization’’ is
generally ‘‘any not-for-profit enterprise
which is independently owned and
operated and is not dominant in its
field.’’
1. Total Small Entities
344. Small Entities, Small
Organizations, Small Governmental
Jurisdictions. Our actions, over time,
may affect small entities that are not
easily categorized at present. We
therefore describe here, at the outset,
three comprehensive small entity size
standards that could be directly affected
herein. First, while there are industry
specific size standards for small
businesses that are used in the
regulatory flexibility analysis, according
to data from the SBA’s Office of
Advocacy, in general a small business is
an independent business having fewer
than 500 employees. These types of
PO 00000
Frm 00065
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
7915
small businesses represent 99.9 percent
of all businesses in the United States
which translates to 28.8 million
businesses. Next, the type of small
entity described as a ‘‘small
organization’’ is generally ‘‘any not-forprofit enterprise which is independently
owned and operated and is not
dominant in its field.’’ Nationwide, as of
August 2016, there were approximately
356,494 small organizations based on
registration and tax data filed by
nonprofits with the Internal Revenue
Service (IRS). Finally, the small entity
described as a ‘‘small governmental
jurisdiction’’ is defined generally as
‘‘governments of cities, towns,
townships, villages, school districts, or
special districts, with a population of
less than fifty thousand.’’ U.S. Census
Bureau data from the 2012 Census of
Governments indicates that there were
90,056 local governmental jurisdictions
consisting of general purpose
governments and special purpose
governments in the United States. Of
this number there were 37,132 General
purpose governments (county,
municipal and town or township) with
populations of less than 50,000 and
12,184 Special purpose governments
(independent school districts and
special districts) with populations of
less than 50,000. The 2012 U.S. Census
Bureau data for most types of
governments in the local government
category shows that the majority of
these governments have populations of
less than 50,000. Based on this data we
estimate that at least 49,316 local
government jurisdictions fall in the
category of ‘‘small governmental
jurisdictions.’’
2. Broadband Internet Access Service
Providers
345. The rules we adopt apply to
broadband internet access service
providers. The Economic Census places
these firms, whose services might
include Voice over Internet Protocol
(VoIP), in either of two categories,
depending on whether the service is
provided over the provider’s own
telecommunications facilities (e.g., cable
and DSL ISPs), or over client-supplied
telecommunications connections (e.g.,
dial-up ISPs). The former are within the
category of Wired Telecommunications
Carriers, which has an SBA small
business size standard of 1,500 or fewer
employees. These are also labeled
‘‘broadband.’’ The latter are within the
category of All Other
Telecommunications, which has a size
standard of annual receipts of $32.5
million or less. These are labeled nonbroadband. Census data for 2012 show
that there were 3,117 firms that operated
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
7916
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
that year. Of this total, 3,083 operated
with fewer than 1,000 employees. For
the second category, census data for
2012 show that there were 1,442 firms
that operated for the entire year. Of
those firms, a total of 1,400 had annual
receipts less than $25 million.
Consequently, we estimate that the
majority of broadband internet access
service provider firms are small entities.
346. The broadband internet access
service provider industry has changed
since this definition was introduced in
2007. The data cited above may
therefore include entities that no longer
provide broadband internet access
service, and may exclude entities that
now provide such service. To ensure
that this FRFA describes the universe of
small entities that our action might
affect, we discuss in turn several
different types of entities that might be
providing broadband internet access
service. We note that, although we have
no specific information on the number
of small entities that provide broadband
internet access service over unlicensed
spectrum, we include these entities in
our Initial Regulatory Flexibility
Analysis.
3. Wireline Providers
347. Wired Telecommunications
Carriers. The U.S. Census Bureau
defines this industry as ‘‘establishments
primarily engaged in operating and/or
providing access to transmission
facilities and infrastructure that they
own and/or lease for the transmission of
voice, data, text, sound, and video using
wired communications networks.
Transmission facilities may be based on
a single technology or a combination of
technologies. Establishments in this
industry use the wired
telecommunications network facilities
that they operate to provide a variety of
services, such as wired telephony
services, including VoIP services, wired
(cable) audio and video programming
distribution, and wired broadband
internet services. By exception,
establishments providing satellite
television distribution services using
facilities and infrastructure that they
operate are included in this industry.’’
The SBA has developed a small
business size standard for Wired
Telecommunications Carriers, which
consists of all such companies having
1,500 or fewer employees. Census data
for 2012 show that there were 3,117
firms that operated that year. Of this
total, 3,083 operated with fewer than
1,000 employees. Thus, under this size
standard, the majority of firms in this
industry can be considered small.
348. Local Exchange Carriers (LECs).
Neither the Commission nor the SBA
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
has developed a size standard for small
businesses specifically applicable to
local exchange services. The closest
applicable NAICS Code category is for
Wired Telecommunications Carriers, as
defined in paragraph 12 of this FRFA.
Under that size standard, such a
business is small if it has 1,500 or fewer
employees. Census data for 2012 show
that there were 3,117 firms that operated
that year. Of this total, 3,083 operated
with fewer than 1,000 employees. The
Commission therefore estimates that
most providers of local exchange carrier
service are small entities that may be
affected by the rules adopted.
349. Incumbent Local Exchange
Carriers (incumbent LECs). Neither the
Commission nor the SBA has developed
a small business size standard
specifically for incumbent local
exchange services. The closest
applicable NAICS Code category is
Wired Telecommunications Carriers as
defined in paragraph 17 of this FRFA.
Under that size standard, such a
business is small if it has 1,500 or fewer
employees. According to Commission
data, 3,117 firms operated in that year.
Of this total, 3,083 operated with fewer
than 1,000 employees. Consequently,
the Commission estimates that most
providers of incumbent local exchange
service are small businesses that may be
affected by the rules and policies
adopted. One thousand three hundred
and seven (1,307) Incumbent Local
Exchange Carriers reported that they
were incumbent local exchange service
providers. Of this total, an estimated
1,006 have 1,500 or fewer employees.
350. Competitive Local Exchange
Carriers (Competitive LECs),
Competitive Access Providers (CAPs),
Shared-Tenant Service Providers, and
Other Local Service Providers. Neither
the Commission nor the SBA has
developed a small business size
standard specifically for these service
providers. The appropriate NAICS Code
category is Wired Telecommunications
Carriers, as defined in paragraph 17 of
this FRFA. Under that size standard,
such a business is small if it has 1,500
or fewer employees. U.S. Census data
for 2012 indicate that 3,117 firms
operated during that year. Of that
number, 3,083 operated with fewer than
1,000 employees. Based on this data, the
Commission concludes that the majority
of Competitive LECs, CAPs, SharedTenant Service Providers, and Other
Local Service Providers are small
entities. According to Commission data,
1,442 carriers reported that they were
engaged in the provision of either
competitive local exchange services or
competitive access provider services. Of
these 1,442 carriers, an estimated 1,256
PO 00000
Frm 00066
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
have 1,500 or fewer employees. In
addition, 17 carriers have reported that
they are Shared-Tenant Service
Providers, and all 17 are estimated to
have 1,500 or fewer employees. In
addition, 72 carriers have reported that
they are Other Local Service Providers.
Of this total, 70 have 1,500 or fewer
employees. Consequently, the
Commission estimates that most
providers of competitive local exchange
service, competitive access providers,
Shared-Tenant Service Providers, and
Other Local Service Providers are small
entities that may be affected by the
adopted rules.
351. We have included small
incumbent LECs in this present RFA
analysis. As noted above, a ‘‘small
business’’ under the RFA is one that,
inter alia, meets the pertinent small
business size standard (e.g., a telephone
communications business having 1,500
or fewer employees), and ‘‘is not
dominant in its field of operation.’’ The
SBA’s Office of Advocacy contends that,
for RFA purposes, small incumbent
LECs are not dominant in their field of
operation because any such dominance
is not ‘‘national’’ in scope. We have
therefore included small incumbent
LECs in this RFA analysis, although we
emphasize that this RFA action has no
effect on Commission analyses and
determinations in other, non-RFA
contexts.
352. Interexchange Carriers (IXCs).
Neither the Commission nor the SBA
has developed a definition for
Interexchange Carriers. The closest
NAICS Code category is Wired
Telecommunications Carriers as defined
in paragraph 17 of this FRFA. The
applicable size standard under SBA
rules is that such a business is small if
it has 1,500 or fewer employees.
According to Commission data, 359
companies reported that their primary
telecommunications service activity was
the provision of interexchange services.
Of this total, an estimated 317 have
1,500 or fewer employees and 42 have
more than 1,500 employees.
Consequently, the Commission
estimates that the majority of
interexchange service providers are
small entities that may be affected by
rules adopted.
353. Operator Service Providers
(OSPs). Neither the Commission nor the
SBA has developed a small business
size standard specifically for operator
service providers. The appropriate size
standard under SBA rules is for the
category Wired Telecommunications
Carriers. Under that size standard, such
a business is small if it has 1,500 or
fewer employees. According to
Commission data, 33 carriers have
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
reported that they are engaged in the
provision of operator services. Of these,
an estimated 31 have 1,500 or fewer
employees and two have more than
1,500 employees. Consequently, the
Commission estimates that the majority
of OSPs are small entities that may be
affected by our adopted rules.
354. Other Toll Carriers. Neither the
Commission nor the SBA has developed
a definition for small businesses
specifically applicable to Other Toll
Carriers. This category includes toll
carriers that do not fall within the
categories of interexchange carriers,
operator service providers, prepaid
calling card providers, satellite service
carriers, or toll resellers. The closest
applicable NAICS Code category is for
Wired Telecommunications Carriers as
defined above. Under the applicable
SBA size standard, such a business is
small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees.
Census data for 2012 shows that there
were 3,117 firms that operated that year.
Of this total, 3,083 operated with fewer
than 1,000 employees. Thus, under this
category and the associated small
business size standard, the majority of
Other Toll Carriers can be considered
small. According to internally
developed Commission data, 284
companies reported that their primary
telecommunications service activity was
the provision of other toll carriage. Of
these, an estimated 279 have 1,500 or
fewer employees. Consequently, the
Commission estimates that most Other
Toll Carriers are small entities that may
be affected by rules adopted pursuant to
the Order.
4. Wireless Providers—Fixed and
Mobile
355. The broadband internet access
service provider category covered by
these rules may cover multiple wireless
firms and categories of regulated
wireless services. Thus, to the extent the
wireless services listed below are used
by wireless firms for broadband internet
access service, the proposed actions
may have an impact on those small
businesses as set forth above and further
below. In addition, for those services
subject to auctions, we note that, as a
general matter, the number of winning
bidders that claim to qualify as small
businesses at the close of an auction
does not necessarily represent the
number of small businesses currently in
service. Also, the Commission does not
generally track subsequent business size
unless, in the context of assignments
and transfers or reportable eligibility
events, unjust enrichment issues are
implicated.
356. Wireless Telecommunications
Carriers (except Satellite). This industry
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
comprises establishments engaged in
operating and maintaining switching
and transmission facilities to provide
communications via the airwaves, such
as cellular services, paging services,
wireless internet access, and wireless
video services. The appropriate size
standard under SBA rules is that such
a business is small if it has 1,500 or
fewer employees. For this industry,
Census data for 2012 show that there
were 967 firms that operated for the
entire year. Of this total, 955 firms had
fewer than 1,000 employees. Thus
under this category and the associated
size standard, the Commission estimates
that the majority of wireless
telecommunications carriers (except
satellite) are small entities. Similarly,
according to internally developed
Commission data, 413 carriers reported
that they were engaged in the provision
of wireless telephony, including cellular
service, Personal Communications
Service (PCS), and Specialized Mobile
Radio (SMR) services. Of this total, an
estimated 261 have 1,500 or fewer
employees. Consequently, the
Commission estimates that
approximately half of these firms can be
considered small. Thus, using available
data, we estimate that the majority of
wireless firms can be considered small.
357. The Commission’s own data—
available in its Universal Licensing
System—indicate that, as of October 25,
2016, there are 280 Cellular licensees
that will be affected by our actions
today. The Commission does not know
how many of these licensees are small,
as the Commission does not collect that
information for these types of entities.
Similarly, according to internally
developed Commission data, 413
carriers reported that they were engaged
in the provision of wireless telephony,
including cellular service, Personal
Communications Service, and
Specialized Mobile Radio Telephony
services. Of this total, an estimated 261
have 1,500 or fewer employees, and 152
have more than 1,500 employees. Thus,
using available data, we estimate that
the majority of wireless firms can be
considered small.
358. Wireless Communications
Services. This service can be used for
fixed, mobile, radiolocation, and digital
audio broadcasting satellite uses. The
Commission defined ‘‘small business’’
for the wireless communications
services (WCS) auction as an entity with
average gross revenues of $40 million
for each of the three preceding years,
and a ‘‘very small business’’ as an entity
with average gross revenues of $15
million for each of the three preceding
years. The SBA has approved these
definitions.
PO 00000
Frm 00067
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
7917
359. 1670–1675 MHz Services. This
service can be used for fixed and mobile
uses, except aeronautical mobile. An
auction for one license in the 1670–1675
MHz band was conducted in 2003. One
license was awarded. The winning
bidder was not a small entity.
360. Wireless Telephony. Wireless
telephony includes cellular, personal
communications services, and
specialized mobile radio telephony
carriers. As noted, the SBA has
developed a small business size
standard for Wireless
Telecommunications Carriers (except
Satellite). Under the SBA small business
size standard, a business is small if it
has 1,500 or fewer employees.
According to Commission data, 413
carriers reported that they were engaged
in wireless telephony. Of these, an
estimated 261 have 1,500 or fewer
employees and 152 have more than
1,500 employees. Therefore, a little less
than one third of these entities can be
considered small.
361. Broadband Personal
Communications Service. The
broadband personal communications
services (PCS) spectrum is divided into
six frequency blocks designated A
through F, and the Commission has held
auctions for each block. The
Commission initially defined a ‘‘small
business’’ for C- and F-Block licenses as
an entity that has average gross revenues
of $40 million or less in the three
previous calendar years. For F-Block
licenses, an additional small business
size standard for ‘‘very small business’’
was added and is defined as an entity
that, together with its affiliates, has
average gross revenues of not more than
$15 million for the preceding three
calendar years. These small business
size standards, in the context of
broadband PCS auctions, have been
approved by the SBA. No small
businesses within the SBA-approved
small business size standards bid
successfully for licenses in Blocks A
and B. There were 90 winning bidders
that claimed small business status in the
first two C-Block auctions. A total of 93
bidders that claimed small business
status won approximately 40 percent of
the 1,479 licenses in the first auction for
the D, E, and F Blocks. On April 15,
1999, the Commission completed the
reauction of 347 C-, D-, E-, and F-Block
licenses in Auction No. 22. Of the 57
winning bidders in that auction, 48
claimed small business status and won
277 licenses.
362. On January 26, 2001, the
Commission completed the auction of
422 C and F Block Broadband PCS
licenses in Auction No. 35. Of the 35
winning bidders in that auction, 29
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
7918
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
claimed small business status.
Subsequent events concerning Auction
35, including judicial and agency
determinations, resulted in a total of 163
C and F Block licenses being available
for grant. On February 15, 2005, the
Commission completed an auction of
242 C-, D-, E-, and F-Block licenses in
Auction No. 58. Of the 24 winning
bidders in that auction, 16 claimed
small business status and won 156
licenses. On May 21, 2007, the
Commission completed an auction of 33
licenses in the A, C, and F Blocks in
Auction No. 71. Of the 12 winning
bidders in that auction, five claimed
small business status and won 18
licenses. On August 20, 2008, the
Commission completed the auction of
20 C-, D-, E-, and F-Block Broadband
PCS licenses in Auction No. 78. Of the
eight winning bidders for Broadband
PCS licenses in that auction, six claimed
small business status and won 14
licenses.
363. Specialized Mobile Radio
Licenses. The Commission awards
‘‘small entity’’ bidding credits in
auctions for Specialized Mobile Radio
(SMR) geographic area licenses in the
800 MHz and 900 MHz bands to firms
that had revenues of no more than $15
million in each of the three previous
calendar years. The Commission awards
‘‘very small entity’’ bidding credits to
firms that had revenues of no more than
$3 million in each of the three previous
calendar years. The SBA has approved
these small business size standards for
the 900 MHz Service. The Commission
has held auctions for geographic area
licenses in the 800 MHz and 900 MHz
bands. The 900 MHz SMR auction began
on December 5, 1995, and closed on
April 15, 1996. Sixty bidders claiming
that they qualified as small businesses
under the $15 million size standard won
263 geographic area licenses in the 900
MHz SMR band. The 800 MHz SMR
auction for the upper 200 channels
began on October 28, 1997, and was
completed on December 8, 1997. Ten
bidders claiming that they qualified as
small businesses under the $15 million
size standard won 38 geographic area
licenses for the upper 200 channels in
the 800 MHz SMR band. A second
auction for the 800 MHz band was held
on January 10, 2002 and closed on
January 17, 2002 and included 23 BEA
licenses. One bidder claiming small
business status won five licenses.
364. The auction of the 1,053 800
MHz SMR geographic area licenses for
the General Category channels began on
August 16, 2000, and was completed on
September 1, 2000. Eleven bidders won
108 geographic area licenses for the
General Category channels in the 800
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
MHz SMR band and qualified as small
businesses under the $15 million size
standard. In an auction completed on
December 5, 2000, a total of 2,800
Economic Area licenses in the lower 80
channels of the 800 MHz SMR service
were awarded. Of the 22 winning
bidders, 19 claimed small business
status and won 129 licenses. Thus,
combining all four auctions, 41 winning
bidders for geographic licenses in the
800 MHz SMR band claimed status as
small businesses.
365. In addition, there are numerous
incumbent site-by-site SMR licenses and
licensees with extended implementation
authorizations in the 800 and 900 MHz
bands. We do not know how many firms
provide 800 MHz or 900 MHz
geographic area SMR service pursuant
to extended implementation
authorizations, nor how many of these
providers have annual revenues of no
more than $15 million. One firm has
over $15 million in revenues. In
addition, we do not know how many of
these firms have 1,500 or fewer
employees, which is the SBAdetermined size standard. We assume,
for purposes of this analysis, that all of
the remaining extended implementation
authorizations are held by small
entities, as defined by the SBA.
366. Lower 700 MHz Band Licenses.
The Commission previously adopted
criteria for defining three groups of
small businesses for purposes of
determining their eligibility for special
provisions such as bidding credits. The
Commission defined a ‘‘small business’’
as an entity that, together with its
affiliates and controlling principals, has
average gross revenues not exceeding
$40 million for the preceding three
years. A ‘‘very small business’’ is
defined as an entity that, together with
its affiliates and controlling principals,
has average gross revenues that are not
more than $15 million for the preceding
three years. Additionally, the lower 700
MHz Service had a third category of
small business status for Metropolitan/
Rural Service Area (MSA/RSA)
licenses—‘‘entrepreneur’’—which is
defined as an entity that, together with
its affiliates and controlling principals,
has average gross revenues that are not
more than $3 million for the preceding
three years. The SBA approved these
small size standards. An auction of 740
licenses (one license in each of the 734
MSAs/RSAs and one license in each of
the six Economic Area Groupings
(EAGs)) commenced on August 27,
2002, and closed on September 18,
2002. Of the 740 licenses available for
auction, 484 licenses were won by 102
winning bidders. Seventy-two of the
winning bidders claimed small
PO 00000
Frm 00068
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
business, very small business or
entrepreneur status and won a total of
329 licenses. A second auction
commenced on May 28, 2003, closed on
June 13, 2003, and included 256
licenses: 5 EAG licenses and 476
Cellular Market Area licenses.
Seventeen winning bidders claimed
small or very small business status and
won 60 licenses, and nine winning
bidders claimed entrepreneur status and
won 154 licenses. On July 26, 2005, the
Commission completed an auction of 5
licenses in the Lower 700 MHz band
(Auction No. 60). There were three
winning bidders for five licenses. All
three winning bidders claimed small
business status.
367. In 2007, the Commission
reexamined its rules governing the 700
MHz band in the 700 MHz Second
Report and Order. An auction of 700
MHz licenses commenced January 24,
2008 and closed on March 18, 2008,
which included, 176 Economic Area
licenses in the A Block, 734 Cellular
Market Area licenses in the B Block, and
176 EA licenses in the E Block. Twenty
winning bidders, claiming small
business status (those with attributable
average annual gross revenues that
exceed $15 million and do not exceed
$40 million for the preceding three
years) won 49 licenses. Thirty three
winning bidders claiming very small
business status (those with attributable
average annual gross revenues that do
not exceed $15 million for the preceding
three years) won 325 licenses.
368. Upper 700 MHz Band Licenses.
In the 700 MHz Second Report and
Order, the Commission revised its rules
regarding Upper 700 MHz licenses. On
January 24, 2008, the Commission
commenced Auction 73 in which
several licenses in the Upper 700 MHz
band were available for licensing: 12
Regional Economic Area Grouping
licenses in the C Block, and one
nationwide license in the D Block. The
auction concluded on March 18, 2008,
with 3 winning bidders claiming very
small business status (those with
attributable average annual gross
revenues that do not exceed $15 million
for the preceding three years) and
winning five licenses.
369. 700 MHz Guard Band Licensees.
In 2000, in the 700 MHz Guard Band
Order, the Commission adopted size
standards for ‘‘small businesses’’ and
‘‘very small businesses’’ for purposes of
determining their eligibility for special
provisions such as bidding credits and
installment payments. A small business
in this service is an entity that, together
with its affiliates and controlling
principals, has average gross revenues
not exceeding $40 million for the
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
preceding three years. Additionally, a
very small business is an entity that,
together with its affiliates and
controlling principals, has average gross
revenues that are not more than $15
million for the preceding three years.
SBA approval of these definitions is not
required. An auction of 52 Major
Economic Area licenses commenced on
September 6, 2000, and closed on
September 21, 2000. Of the 104 licenses
auctioned, 96 licenses were sold to nine
bidders. Five of these bidders were
small businesses that won a total of 26
licenses. A second auction of 700 MHz
Guard Band licenses commenced on
February 13, 2001, and closed on
February 21, 2001. All eight of the
licenses auctioned were sold to three
bidders. One of these bidders was a
small business that won a total of two
licenses.
370. Air-Ground Radiotelephone
Service. The Commission has previously
used the SBA’s small business size
standard applicable to Wireless
Telecommunications Carriers (except
Satellite), i.e., an entity employing no
more than 1,500 persons. There are
approximately 100 licensees in the AirGround Radiotelephone Service, and
under that definition, we estimate that
almost all of them qualify as small
entities under the SBA definition. For
purposes of assigning Air-Ground
Radiotelephone Service licenses
through competitive bidding, the
Commission has defined ‘‘small
business’’ as an entity that, together
with controlling interests and affiliates,
has average annual gross revenues for
the preceding three years not exceeding
$40 million. A ‘‘very small business’’ is
defined as an entity that, together with
controlling interests and affiliates, has
average annual gross revenues for the
preceding three years not exceeding $15
million. These definitions were
approved by the SBA. In May 2006, the
Commission completed an auction of
nationwide commercial Air-Ground
Radiotelephone Service licenses in the
800 MHz band (Auction No. 65). On
June 2, 2006, the auction closed with
two winning bidders winning two AirGround Radiotelephone Services
licenses. Neither of the winning bidders
claimed small business status.
371. AWS Services (1710–1755 MHz
and 2110–2155 MHz bands (AWS–1);
1915–1920 MHz, 1995–2000 MHz, 2020–
2025 MHz and 2175–2180 MHz bands
(AWS–2); 2155–2175 MHz band (AWS–
3)). For the AWS–1 bands, the
Commission has defined a ‘‘small
business’’ as an entity with average
annual gross revenues for the preceding
three years not exceeding $40 million,
and a ‘‘very small business’’ as an entity
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
with average annual gross revenues for
the preceding three years not exceeding
$15 million. For AWS–2 and AWS–3,
although we do not know for certain
which entities are likely to apply for
these frequencies, we note that the
AWS–1 bands are comparable to those
used for cellular service and personal
communications service. The
Commission has not yet adopted size
standards for the AWS–2 or AWS–3
bands but proposes to treat both AWS–
2 and AWS–3 similarly to broadband
PCS service and AWS–1 service due to
the comparable capital requirements
and other factors, such as issues
involved in relocating incumbents and
developing markets, technologies, and
services.
372. 3650–3700 MHz band. In March
2005, the Commission released a Report
and Order and Memorandum Opinion
and Order that provides for nationwide,
non-exclusive licensing of terrestrial
operations, utilizing contention-based
technologies, in the 3650 MHz band
(i.e., 3650–3700 MHz). As of April 2010,
more than 1270 licenses have been
granted and more than 7433 sites have
been registered. The Commission has
not developed a definition of small
entities applicable to 3650–3700 MHz
band nationwide, non-exclusive
licensees. However, we estimate that the
majority of these licensees are Internet
Access Service Providers (ISPs) and that
most of those licensees are small
businesses.
373. Fixed Microwave Services.
Microwave services include common
carrier, private-operational fixed, and
broadcast auxiliary radio services. They
also include the Local Multipoint
Distribution Service (LMDS), the Digital
Electronic Message Service (DEMS), and
the 24 GHz Service, where licensees can
choose between common carrier and
non-common carrier status. At present,
there are approximately 36,708 common
carrier fixed licensees and 59,291
private operational-fixed licensees and
broadcast auxiliary radio licensees in
the microwave services. There are
approximately 135 LMDS licensees,
three DEMS licensees, and three 24 GHz
licensees. The Commission has not yet
defined a small business with respect to
microwave services. For purposes of the
IRFA, we will use the SBA’s definition
applicable to Wireless
Telecommunications Carriers (except
satellite)—i.e., an entity with no more
than 1,500 persons. Under the present
and prior categories, the SBA has
deemed a wireless business to be small
if it has 1,500 or fewer employees. The
Commission does not have data
specifying the number of these licensees
that have more than 1,500 employees,
PO 00000
Frm 00069
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
7919
and thus is unable at this time to
estimate with greater precision the
number of fixed microwave service
licensees that would qualify as small
business concerns under the SBA’s
small business size standard.
Consequently, the Commission
estimates that there are up to 36,708
common carrier fixed licensees and up
to 59,291 private operational-fixed
licensees and broadcast auxiliary radio
licensees in the microwave services that
may be small and may be affected by the
rules and policies adopted herein. We
note, however, that the common carrier
microwave fixed licensee category
includes some large entities.
374. Broadband Radio Service and
Educational Broadband Service.
Broadband Radio Service systems,
previously referred to as Multipoint
Distribution Service (MDS) and
Multichannel Multipoint Distribution
Service (MMDS) systems, and ‘‘wireless
cable,’’ transmit video programming to
subscribers and provide two-way high
speed data operations using the
microwave frequencies of the
Broadband Radio Service (BRS) and
Educational Broadband Service (EBS)
(previously referred to as the
Instructional Television Fixed Service
(ITFS)). In connection with the 1996
BRS auction, the Commission
established a small business size
standard as an entity that had annual
average gross revenues of no more than
$40 million in the previous three
calendar years. The BRS auctions
resulted in 67 successful bidders
obtaining licensing opportunities for
493 Basic Trading Areas (BTAs). Of the
67 auction winners, 61 met the
definition of a small business. BRS also
includes licensees of stations authorized
prior to the auction. At this time, we
estimate that of the 61 small business
BRS auction winners, 48 remain small
business licensees. In addition to the 48
small businesses that hold BTA
authorizations, there are approximately
392 incumbent BRS licensees that are
considered small entities. After adding
the number of small business auction
licensees to the number of incumbent
licensees not already counted, we find
that there are currently approximately
440 BRS licensees that are defined as
small businesses under either the SBA
or the Commission’s rules.
375. In 2009, the Commission
conducted Auction 86, the sale of 78
licenses in the BRS areas. The
Commission offered three levels of
bidding credits: (i) A bidder with
attributed average annual gross revenues
that exceed $15 million and do not
exceed $40 million for the preceding
three years (small business) received a
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
7920
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
15 percent discount on its winning bid;
(ii) a bidder with attributed average
annual gross revenues that exceed $3
million and do not exceed $15 million
for the preceding three years (very small
business) received a 25 percent discount
on its winning bid; and (iii) a bidder
with attributed average annual gross
revenues that do not exceed $3 million
for the preceding three years
(entrepreneur) received a 35 percent
discount on its winning bid. Auction 86
concluded in 2009 with the sale of 61
licenses. Of the ten winning bidders,
two bidders that claimed small business
status won 4 licenses; one bidder that
claimed very small business status won
three licenses; and two bidders that
claimed entrepreneur status won six
licenses.
5. Satellite Service Providers
376. Satellite Telecommunications
Providers. Two economic census
categories address the satellite industry.
Both categories have a small business
size standard of $32.5 million or less in
average annual receipts, under SBA
rules.
377. Satellite Telecommunications.
This category comprises firms
‘‘primarily engaged in providing
telecommunications services to other
establishments in the
telecommunications and broadcasting
industries by forwarding and receiving
communications signals via a system of
satellites or reselling satellite
telecommunications.’’ The category has
a small business size standard of $32.5
million or less in average annual
receipts, under SBA rules. For this
category, Census Bureau data for 2012
show that there were a total of 333 firms
that operated for the entire year. Of this
total, 299 firms had annual receipts of
less than $25 million. Consequently, we
estimate that the majority of satellite
telecommunications providers are small
entities.
378. All Other Telecommunications.
‘‘All Other Telecommunications’’ is
defined as follows: ‘‘This U.S. industry
is comprised of establishments that are
primarily engaged in providing
specialized telecommunications
services, such as satellite tracking,
communications telemetry, and radar
station operation. This industry also
includes establishments primarily
engaged in providing satellite terminal
stations and associated facilities
connected with one or more terrestrial
systems and capable of transmitting
telecommunications to, and receiving
telecommunications from, satellite
systems. Establishments providing
internet services or voice over internet
protocol (VoIP) services via client
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
supplied telecommunications
connections are also included in this
industry.’’ The SBA has developed a
small business size standard for ‘‘All
Other Telecommunications,’’ which
consists of all such firms with gross
annual receipts of $32.5 million or less.
For this category, Census Bureau data
for 2012 show that there were 1,442
firms that operated for the entire year.
Of those firms, a total of 1,400 had
annual receipts less than $25 million.
Consequently, we conclude that the
majority of All Other
Telecommunications firms can be
considered small.
6. Cable Service Providers
379. Because Section 706 requires us
to monitor the deployment of broadband
using any technology, we anticipate that
some broadband service providers may
not provide telephone service.
Accordingly, we describe below other
types of firms that may provide
broadband services, including cable
companies, MDS providers, and
utilities, among others.
380. Cable and Other Subscription
Programming. This industry comprises
establishments primarily engaged in
operating studios and facilities for the
broadcasting of programs on a
subscription or fee basis. The broadcast
programming is typically narrowcast in
nature (e.g., limited format, such as
news, sports, education, or youthoriented). These establishments produce
programming in their own facilities or
acquire programming from external
sources. The programming material is
usually delivered to a third party, such
as cable systems or direct-to-home
satellite systems, for transmission to
viewers. The SBA size standard for this
industry establishes as small, any
company in this category which has
annual receipts of $38.5 million or less.
According to 2012 U.S. Census Bureau
data, 367 firms operated for the entire
year. Of that number, 319 operated with
annual receipts of less than $25 million
a year and 48 firms operated with
annual receipts of $25 million or more.
Based on this data, the Commission
estimates that the majority of firms
operating in this industry are small.
381. Cable Companies and Systems
(Rate Regulation). The Commission has
developed its own small business size
standards for the purpose of cable rate
regulation. Under the Commission’s
rules, a ‘‘small cable company’’ is one
serving 400,000 or fewer subscribers
nationwide. Industry data indicate that
there are currently 4,600 active cable
systems in the United States. Of this
total, all but nine cable operators
nationwide are small under the 400,000-
PO 00000
Frm 00070
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
subscriber size standard. In addition,
under the Commission’s rate regulation
rules, a ‘‘small system’’ is a cable system
serving 15,000 or fewer subscribers.
Current Commission records show 4,600
cable systems nationwide. Of this total,
3,900 cable systems have fewer than
15,000 subscribers, and 700 systems
have 15,000 or more subscribers, based
on the same records. Thus, under this
standard as well, we estimate that most
cable systems are small entities.
382. Cable System Operators
(Telecom Act Standard). The
Communications Act of 1934, as
amended, also contains a size standard
for small cable system operators, which
is ‘‘a cable operator that, directly or
through an affiliate, serves in the
aggregate fewer than one percent of all
subscribers in the United States and is
not affiliated with any entity or entities
whose gross annual revenues in the
aggregate exceed $250,000,000 are
approximately 52,403,705 cable video
subscribers in the United States today.
Accordingly, an operator serving fewer
than 524,037 subscribers shall be
deemed a small operator if its annual
revenues, when combined with the total
annual revenues of all its affiliates, do
not exceed $250 million in the
aggregate. Based on available data, we
find that all but nine incumbent cable
operators are small entities under this
size standard. We note that the
Commission neither requests nor
collects information on whether cable
system operators are affiliated with
entities whose gross annual revenues
exceed $250 million. Although it seems
certain that some of these cable system
operators are affiliated with entities
whose gross annual revenues exceed
$250,000,000, we are unable at this time
to estimate with greater precision the
number of cable system operators that
would qualify as small cable operators
under the definition in the
Communications Act.
7. All Other Telecommunications
383. ‘‘All Other Telecommunications’’
is defined as follows: ‘‘This U.S.
industry is comprised of establishments
that are primarily engaged in providing
specialized telecommunications
services, such as satellite tracking,
communications telemetry, and radar
station operation. This industry also
includes establishments primarily
engaged in providing satellite terminal
stations and associated facilities
connected with one or more terrestrial
systems and capable of transmitting
telecommunications to, and receiving
telecommunications from, satellite
systems. Establishments providing
internet services or voice over internet
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
protocol (VoIP) services via client
supplied telecommunications
connections are also included in this
industry.’’ The SBA has developed a
small business size standard for ‘‘All
Other Telecommunications,’’ which
consists of all such firms with gross
annual receipts of $32.5 million or less.
For this category, Census Bureau data
for 2012 show that there were 1,442
firms that operated for the entire year.
Of those firms, a total of 1,400 had
annual receipts less than $25 million.
Consequently, we conclude that the
majority of All Other
Telecommunications firms can be
considered small.
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
E. Description of Projected Reporting,
Recordkeeping, and Other Compliance
Requirements for Small Entities
384. Today’s action requires
broadband internet access service
providers to ‘‘publicly disclose accurate
information regarding the network
management practices, performance,
and commercial terms of its broadband
internet access services sufficient to
enable consumers to make informed
choices regarding the purchase and use
of such services and entrepreneurs and
other small businesses to develop,
market, and maintain internet
offerings.’’
385. Broadband internet access
service providers must disclose
performance characteristics, network
practices, and commercial terms. The
required disclosures must either be
posted on a publicly available, easily
accessible website, or they must be
submitted to the Commission, which
will post the disclosures on a publicly
available, easily accessible website.
386. Because the disclosure
requirements we adopt today eliminate
the additional reporting obligations
found in the Title II Order, we decline
to provide an exemption for smaller
providers at this time. While a
commenter emphasized that small
broadband internet access service
providers had an even more pressing
need to be classified as information
service providers, today’s action applies
equally to all providers of broadband
internet access service, and therefore
does even more than the initial
comment requested.
F. Steps Taken To Minimize the
Significant Economic Impact on Small
Entities, and Significant Alternatives
Considered
387. Today’s action restores
broadband internet access service’s
original classification as an information
service. This will significantly decrease
the burdens on small entities.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
Additionally, the removal of the
additional reporting obligations, the
direct notification requirement, and the
broadband provider safe harbor form
will minimize the burdens providers
face.
388. The transparency rule we adopt
today strikes an appropriate balance by
requiring ISPs to disclose information
that will allow consumers to make
informed choices and that will enable
the Commission to enable it to meet its
statutory obligation to observe the
communications marketplace to monitor
the introduction of new services and
technologies and to identify and
eliminate potential marketplace barriers
for the provision of information service,
while simultaneously freeing providers
from onerous burdens that produce little
public benefit. While retaining the
transparency rule, with modifications,
from the Open Internet Order, we
eliminate the additional reporting
obligations, the direct notification
requirements, and the broadband label
‘‘safe harbor,’’ all of which will reduce
the burdens on ISPs. The additional
reporting obligations, the direct
notification requirement, and the ‘‘safe
harbor’’ all required ISPs to expend
significant resources without a
corresponding gain to consumers,
entrepreneurs, or other small
businesses.
389. We also eliminate several rules
adopted in the Title II Order, including
the general conduct standard, the ban
on paid prioritization, and the noblocking and no-throttling rules. We
eliminate these rules for three reasons.
First, the transparency rule we adopt, in
combination with the state of broadband
internet access service competition and
the antitrust and consumer protection
laws, obviate the need for conduct rules
by achieving comparable benefits at
lower cost. Second, the record does not
identify any legal authority to adopt
conduct rules for all ISPs, and we
decline to distort the market with a
patchwork of non-uniform, limitedpurpose rules. Third, scrutinizing
closely each prior conduct rule, we find
that the costs of each rule outweigh its
benefits.
390. We also eliminate the position of
Open Internet Ombudsperson, the
formal complaint process, and the
issuance of advisory opinions, because
the work of the Open Internet
Ombudsperson is more appropriately
handled by Commission staff, and
because the issuance of advisory
opinions and the formal complaint
process have not been shown to provide
any benefit to broadband internet access
service providers or consumers.
PO 00000
Frm 00071
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
7921
391. Finally, we return mobile
broadband internet access service to its
original classification as a private
mobile radio service and restore the
definition of interconnected service that
existed prior to the Title II Order. This
will remove regulatory burdens from
providers of mobile broadband internet
access service, including small
providers.
G. Report to Congress
392. The Commission will send a
copy of this Declaratory Ruling, Report
and Order, and Order, including this
FRFA, in a report to be sent to Congress
pursuant to the SBREFA. In addition,
the Commission will send a copy of this
Declaratory Ruling, Report and Order,
and Order, including the FRFA, to the
Chief Counsel for Advocacy of the SBA.
A copy of the Declaratory Ruling, Report
and Order, and Order, and the FRFA (or
summaries thereof) will also be
published in the Federal Register.
VII. Ordering Clauses
393. Accordingly, it is ordered that,
pursuant to Sections 3, 4, 201(b), 230,
231, 257, 303, 332, 403, 501, and 503 of
the Communications Act of 1934, as
amended, 47 U.S.C. 153, 154, 201(b),
230, 231, 257, 303, 332, 403, 501, 503,
this Declaratory Ruling, Report and
Order, and Order is adopted.
394. It is further ordered that parts 1,
8, and 20 of the Commission’s rules are
amended as set forth in the Final Rules
of the Order.
395. It is further ordered that this
Declaratory Ruling, Report and Order,
and Order, including those amendments
which contain new or modified
information collection requirements that
require approval by the Office of
Management and Budget (OMB) under
the Paperwork Reduction Act will
become effective upon the effective date
announced when the Commission
publishes a document in the Federal
Register announcing such OMB
approval and the effective date. It is our
intention in adopting the foregoing
Declaratory Ruling and these rule
changes that, if any provision of the
Declaratory Ruling or the rules, or the
application thereof to any person or
circumstance, is held to be unlawful,
the remaining portions of such
Declaratory Ruling and the rules not
deemed unlawful, and the application
of such Declaratory Ruling and the rules
to other person or circumstances, shall
remain in effect to the fullest extent
permitted by law.
396. It is further ordered that the
incompas Petition to Modify Protective
Orders is denied.
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
7922
Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 / Rules and Regulations
397. It is further ordered that the
National Hispanic Media Coalition
(NHMC) Motion Regarding Informal
Consumer Complaints is denied.
398. It is further ordered that the
Commission’s Consumer &
Governmental Affairs Bureau, Reference
Information Center, shall send a copy of
this Declaratory Ruling, Report and
Order, and Order to Congress and the
Government Accountability Office
pursuant to the Congressional Review
Act, see 5 U.S.C. 801(a)(1)(A).
399. It is further ordered that,
pursuant to 47 CFR 1.4(b)(1), the period
for filing petitions for reconsideration or
petitions for judicial review of this
Declaratory Ruling, Report and Order,
and Order will commence on the date
that a summary of this Declaratory
Ruling, Report and Order, and Order is
published in the Federal Register.
List of Subjects in 47 CFR Parts 1, 8,
and 20
Administrative practice and
procedure, Cable television, Common
carriers, Communications common
carriers, Reporting and recordkeeping
requirements, Satellites,
Telecommunications, Telephone, Radio.
Federal Communications Commission.
Marlene H. Dortch,
Secretary, Office of the Secretary.
Final Rules
For the reasons discussed in the
preamble, the Federal Communications
Commission amends 47 CFR parts 1, 8,
and 20 as follows:
PART 1—PRACTICE AND
PROCEDURE
1. The authority citation for part 1
continues to read as follows:
■
Authority: 47 U.S.C. 34–39, 151, 154(i),
154(j), 155, 157, 160, 201, 225, 227, 303, 309,
332, 1403, 1404, 1451, 1452, and 1455.
2. Amend § 1.49 by revising paragraph
(f)(1)(i) to read as follows:
■
§ 1.49 Specifications as to pleadings and
documents.
*
*
*
*
(f) * * *
(1) * * *
(i) Formal complaint proceedings
under section 208 of the Act and in
daltland on DSKBBV9HB2PROD with RULES2
*
VerDate Sep<11>2014
21:02 Feb 21, 2018
Jkt 244001
§§ 1.720 through 1.736, and pole
attachment complaint proceedings
under section 224 of the Act and in
§§ 1.1401 through 1.1424;
*
*
*
*
*
§§ 8.2, 8.3, 8.5, 8.7, 8.9, 8.11, 8.12, 8.13, 8.14,
8.15, 8.16, 8.17, 8.18, and 8.19 [Removed]
PART 8—INTERNET FREEDOM
PART 20—COMMERCIAL MOBILE
SERVICES
3. The authority citation for part 8 is
revised to read as follows:
6. Remove §§ 8.2, 8.3, 8.5, 8.7, 8.9,
8.11, 8.12, 8.13, 8.14, 8.15, 8.16, 8.17,
8.18, and 8.19.
■
■
Authority: 47 U.S.C. 154, 201(b), 257, and
303(r).
4. Amend part 8 by revising the part
heading to read as set forth above.
■
■
5. Revise § 8.1 to read as follows:
§ 8.1
Frm 00072
Fmt 4701
Authority: 47 U.S.C. 151, 152(a) 154(i),
157, 160, 201, 214, 222, 251(e), 301, 302, 303,
303(b), 303(r), 307, 307(a), 309, 309(j)(3), 316,
316(a), 332, 610, 615, 615a, 615b, 615c,
unless otherwise noted.
8. Amend § 20.3 by:
a. In the definition of ‘‘Commercial
mobile radio service,’’ revising
paragraph (b);
■ b. In the definition of ‘‘Interconnected
Service,’’ revising paragraph (a); and
■ c. Revising the definition of ‘‘Public
Switched Network.’’
The revisions read as follows:
■
■
Transparency.
(a) Any person providing broadband
internet access service shall publicly
disclose accurate information regarding
the network management practices,
performance characteristics, and
commercial terms of its broadband
internet access services sufficient to
enable consumers to make informed
choices regarding the purchase and use
of such services and entrepreneurs and
other small businesses to develop,
market, and maintain internet offerings.
Such disclosure shall be made via a
publicly available, easily accessible
website or through transmittal to the
Commission.
(b) Broadband internet access service
is a mass-market retail service by wire
or radio that provides the capability to
transmit data to and receive data from
all or substantially all internet
endpoints, including any capabilities
that are incidental to and enable the
operation of the communications
service, but excluding dial-up internet
access service. This term also
encompasses any service that the
Commission finds to be providing a
functional equivalent of the service
described in the previous sentence or
that is used to evade the protections set
forth in this part.
(c) A network management practice is
reasonable if it is appropriate and
tailored to achieving a legitimate
network management purpose, taking
into account the particular network
architecture and technology of the
broadband internet access service.
PO 00000
7. The authority citation for part 20
continues to read as follows:
■
Sfmt 9990
§ 20.3
Definitions.
*
*
*
*
*
Commercial mobile radio service.
* * *
*
*
*
*
*
(b) The functional equivalent of such
a mobile service described in paragraph
(a) of this definition.
*
*
*
*
*
Interconnected Service. * * *
(a) That is interconnected with the
public switched network, or
interconnected with the public switched
network through an interconnected
service provider, that gives subscribers
the capability to communicate to or
receive communication from all other
users on the public switched network;
or
*
*
*
*
*
Public Switched Network. Any
common carrier switched network,
whether by wire or radio, including
local exchange carriers, interexchange
carriers, and mobile service providers,
that uses the North American
Numbering Plan in connection with the
provision of switched services.
*
*
*
*
*
[FR Doc. 2018–03464 Filed 2–21–18; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6712–01–P
E:\FR\FM\22FER2.SGM
22FER2
Agencies
[Federal Register Volume 83, Number 36 (Thursday, February 22, 2018)]
[Rules and Regulations]
[Pages 7852-7922]
From the Federal Register Online via the Government Publishing Office [www.gpo.gov]
[FR Doc No: 2018-03464]
[[Page 7851]]
Vol. 83
Thursday,
No. 36
February 22, 2018
Part II
Federal Communications Commission
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
47 CFR Parts 1, 8, and 20
Restoring Internet Freedom; Final Rule
Federal Register / Vol. 83 , No. 36 / Thursday, February 22, 2018 /
Rules and Regulations
[[Page 7852]]
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION
47 CFR Parts 1, 8, and 20
[WC Docket No. 17-108; FCC 17-166]
Restoring Internet Freedom
AGENCY: Federal Communications Commission.
ACTION: Final rule.
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
SUMMARY: In this document, the Federal Communications Commission
(Commission) returns to the light-touch regulatory scheme that enabled
the internet to develop and thrive for nearly two decades. The
Commission restores the classification of broadband internet access
service as a lightly-regulated information service and reinstates the
private mobile service classification of mobile broadband internet
access service. The Restoring Internet Freedom Order requires internet
service providers (ISPs) to disclose information about their network
management practices, performance characteristics, and commercial terms
of service. Finding that transparency is sufficient to protect the
openness of the internet and that conduct rules have greater costs than
benefits, the Order eliminates the conduct rules imposed by the Title
II Order.
DATES: Effective date: April 23, 2018, except for amendatory
instructions 2, 3, 5, 6, and 8, which are delayed as follows. The FCC
will publish a document in the Federal Register announcing the
effective date(s) of the delayed amendatory instructions, which are
contingent on OMB approval of the modified information collection
requirements in 47 CFR 8.1 (amendatory instruction 5). The Declaratory
Ruling, Report and Order, and Order will also be effective upon the
date announced in that same document.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: Ramesh Nagarajan, Competition Policy
Division, Wireline Competition Bureau, at (202) 418-2582,
fcc.gov">[email protected]fcc.gov. For additional information concerning the
Paperwork Reduction Act information collection requirements contained
in this document, send an email to fcc.gov">[email protected]fcc.gov or contact Nicole Ongele
at (202) 418-2991.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: This is a summary of the Commission's
Declaratory Ruling, Report and Order, and Order (``Restoring Internet
Freedom Order'') in WC Docket No. 17-108, adopted on December 14, 2017
and released on January 4, 2018. The full text of this document is
available at https://apps.fcc.gov/edocs_public/attachmatch/FCC-17-166A1.pdf. The full text is also available for public inspection during
regular business hours in the FCC Reference Information Center, Portals
II, 445 12th Street SW, Room CY-A257, Washington, DC 20554. To request
materials in accessible formats for people with disabilities (e.g.,
braille, large print, electronic files, audio format, etc.) or to
request reasonable accommodations (e.g., accessible format documents,
sign language interpreters, CART, etc.), send an email to
fcc.gov">[email protected]fcc.gov or call the Consumer & Governmental Affairs Bureau at
(202) 418-0530 (voice) or (202) 418-0432 (TTY). The language following
the DATES caption of this preamble is provided to ensure compliance
with 1 CFR 18.17.
Synopsis
In this Declaratory Ruling, Report and Order, and Order, the
Commission restores the light-touch regulatory scheme that fostered the
internet's growth, openness, and freedom. Through these actions, we
advance our critical work to promote broadband deployment in rural
America and infrastructure investment throughout the nation, brighten
the future of innovation both within networks and at their edge, and
move closer to the goal of eliminating the digital divide.
I. Ending Public-Utility Regulation of the Internet
1. We reinstate the information service classification of broadband
internet access service, consistent with the Supreme Court's holding in
Brand X. Based on the record before us, we conclude that the best
reading of the relevant definitional provisions of the Act supports
classifying broadband internet access service as an information
service. Having determined that broadband internet access service,
regardless of whether offered using fixed or mobile technologies, is an
information service under the Act, we also conclude that as an
information service, mobile broadband internet access service should
not be classified as a commercial mobile service or its functional
equivalent. We find that it is well within our legal authority to
classify broadband internet access service as an information service,
and reclassification also comports with applicable law governing agency
decisions to change course. While we find our legal analysis sufficient
on its own to support an information service classification of
broadband internet access service, strong public policy considerations
further weigh in favor of an information service classification. Below,
we find that economic theory, empirical data, and even anecdotal
evidence also counsel against imposing public-utility style regulation
on ISPs. The broader internet ecosystem thrived under the light-touch
regulatory treatment of Title I, with massive investment and innovation
by both ISPs and edge providers, leading to previously unimagined
technological developments and services. We conclude that a return to
Title I classification will facilitate critical broadband investment
and innovation by removing regulatory uncertainty and lowering
compliance costs.
A. Reinstating the Information Service Classification of Broadband
Internet Access Service
1. Scope
2. We continue to define ``broadband internet access service'' as a
mass-market retail service by wire or radio that provides the
capability to transmit data to and receive data from all or
substantially all internet endpoints, including any capabilities that
are incidental to and enable the operation of the communications
service, but excluding dial-up internet access service. By mass market,
we mean services marketed and sold on a standardized basis to
residential customers, small businesses, and other end-user customers
such as schools and libraries. ``Schools'' would include institutions
of higher education to the extent that they purchase these standardized
retail services. For purposes of this definition, ``mass market'' also
includes broadband internet access service purchased with the support
of the E-rate and Rural Healthcare programs, as well as any broadband
internet access service offered using networks supported by the Connect
America Fund (CAF), but does not include enterprise service offerings
or special access services, which are typically offered to larger
organizations through customized or individually negotiated
arrangements.
3. The term ``broadband internet access service'' includes services
provided over any technology platform, including but not limited to
wire, terrestrial wireless (including fixed and mobile wireless
services using licensed or unlicensed spectrum), and satellite. For
purposes of our discussion, we divide the various forms of broadband
internet access service into the two categories of ``fixed'' and
``mobile.'' With these two categories of services--fixed and mobile--we
intend to cover the entire universe of internet access services at
issue in the Commission's
[[Page 7853]]
prior broadband classification decisions, as well as all other
broadband internet access services offered over other technology
platforms that were not addressed by prior classification orders. We
also make clear that our classification finding applies to all
providers of broadband internet access service, as we delineate them
here, regardless of whether they lease or own the facilities used to
provide the service. ``Fixed'' broadband internet access service refers
to a broadband internet access service that serves end users primarily
at fixed endpoints using stationary equipment, such as the modem that
connects an end user's home router, computer, or other internet access
device to the internet. The term encompasses the delivery of fixed
broadband over any medium, including various forms of wired broadband
services (e.g., cable, DSL, fiber), fixed wireless broadband services
(including fixed services using unlicensed spectrum), and fixed
satellite broadband services. ``Mobile'' broadband internet access
service refers to a broadband internet access service that serves end
users primarily using mobile stations. Mobile broadband internet access
includes, among other things, services that use smartphones or mobile-
network-enabled tablets as the primary endpoints for connection to the
internet. The term also encompasses mobile satellite broadband
services. We note that ``public safety services'' as defined in Section
337(f)(1) would not meet the definition of ``broadband internet access
service'' subject to the rules herein given that ``such services are
not made commercially available to the public by the provider'' as a
mass-market retail service.
4. As the Commission found in 2010, broadband internet access
service does not include services offering connectivity to one or a
small number of internet endpoints for a particular device, e.g.,
connectivity bundled with e-readers, heart monitors, or energy
consumption sensors, to the extent the service relates to the
functionality of the device. To the extent these services are provided
by ISPs over last-mile capacity shared with broadband internet access
service, they would be non-broadband internet access service data
services (formerly specialized services). As the Commission found in
both 2010 and 2015, non-broadband internet access service data services
do not fall under the broadband internet access service category. Such
services generally are not used to reach large parts of the internet;
are not a generic platform, but rather a specific applications-level
service; and use some form of network management to isolate the
capacity used by these services from that used by broadband internet
access services. Further, we observe that to the extent ISPs ``use
their broadband infrastructure to provide video and voice services,
those services are regulated in their own right.''
5. Broadband internet access service also does not include virtual
private network (VPN) services, content delivery networks (CDNs),
hosting or data storage services, or internet backbone services (if
those services are separate from broadband internet access service),
consistent with past Commission precedent. The Commission has
historically distinguished these services from ``mass market''
services, as they do not provide the capability to transmit data to and
receive data from all or substantially all internet endpoints. We do
not disturb that finding here. Consistent with past Commissions, we
note that the transparency rule we adopt today applies only so far as
the limits of an ISP's control over the transmission of data to or from
its broadband customers.
6. Finally, we observe that to the extent that coffee shops,
bookstores, airlines, private end-user networks such as libraries and
universities, and other businesses acquire broadband internet access
service from an ISP to enable patrons to access the internet from their
respective establishments, provision of such service by the premise
operator would not itself be considered a broadband internet access
service unless it was offered to patrons as a retail mass market
service, as we define it here. Although not bound by the transparency
rule we adopt today, we encourage premise operators to disclose
relevant restrictions on broadband service they make available to their
patrons. Likewise, when a user employs, for example, a wireless router
or a Wi-Fi hotspot to create a personal Wi-Fi network that is not
intentionally offered for the benefit of others, he or she is not
offering a broadband internet access service under our definition,
because the user is not marketing and selling such service to
residential customers, small business, and other end-user customers
such as schools and libraries.
2. Broadband Internet Access Service is an Information Service Under
the Act
7. In deciding how to classify broadband internet access service,
we find that the best reading of the relevant definitional provisions
of the Act supports classifying broadband internet access service as an
information service. Section 3 of the Act defines an ``information
service'' as ``the offering of a capability for generating, acquiring,
storing, transforming, processing, retrieving, utilizing, or making
available information via telecommunications, and includes electronic
publishing, but does not include any use of any such capability for the
management, control, or operation of a telecommunications system or the
management of a telecommunications service.'' Section 3 defines a
``telecommunications service,'' by contrast, as ``the offering of
telecommunications for a fee directly to the public, or to such classes
of users as to be effectively available directly to the public,
regardless of the facilities used.'' Finally, Section 3 defines
``telecommunications''--used in each of the prior two definitions--as
``the transmission, between or among points specified by the user, of
information of the user's choosing, without change in the form or
content of the information as sent and received.'' Prior to the Title
II Order the Commission had long interpreted and applied these terms to
classify various forms of internet access service as information
services--a conclusion affirmed as reasonable by the Supreme Court in
Brand X. Our action here simply returns to that prior approach.
8. When interpreting a statute it administers, the Commission, like
all agencies, ``must operate `within the bounds of reasonable
interpretation.' And reasonable statutory interpretation must account
for both `the specific context in which . . . language is used' and
`the broader context of the statute as a whole.' '' Below, we first
explore the meaning of the ``capability'' contemplated in the statutory
definition of ``information service,'' and find that broadband internet
access service provides consumers the ``capability'' to engage in all
of the information processes listed in the information service
definition. We also find that broadband internet access service
likewise provides information processing functionalities itself, such
as DNS and caching, which satisfy the capabilities set forth in the
information service definition. We then address what ``capabilities''
we believe are being ``offered'' by ISPs, and whether these are
reasonably viewed as separate from or inextricably intertwined with
transmission, and find that broadband internet access service offerings
inextricably intertwine these information processing capabilities with
transmission.
9. We find that applying our understanding of the statutory
definitions to broadband internet access service as it is offered today
most soundly leads to the conclusion that it
[[Page 7854]]
is an information service. Although the internet marketplace has
continued to develop in the years since the earliest classification
decisions, broadband internet access service offerings still involve a
number of ``capabilities'' within the meaning of the Section 3
definition of information services, including critical capabilities
that all ISP customers must use for the service to work as it does
today. While many popular uses of the internet have shifted over time,
the record reveals that broadband internet access service continues to
offer information service capabilities that typical users both expect
and rely upon. Indeed, the basic nature of internet service--
``[p]rovid[ing] consumers with a comprehensive capability for
manipulating information using the internet via high-speed
telecommunications''--has remained the same since the Supreme Court
upheld the Commission's similar classification of cable modem service
as an information service twelve years ago.
10. A body of precedent from the courts and the Commission served
as the backdrop for the 1996 Act and informed the Commission's original
interpretation and implementation of the statutory definitions of
``telecommunications,'' ``telecommunications service,'' and
``information service.'' The classification decisions in the Title II
Order discounted or ignored much of that precedent. Without viewing
ourselves as formally bound by that prior precedent, we find it
eminently reasonable, as a legal matter, to give significant weight to
that pre-1996 Act precedent in resolving how the statutory definitions
apply to broadband internet access service, enabling us to resolve
statutory ambiguity in a manner that we believe best reflects
Congress's understanding and intent. Our analysis thus is not at odds
with the statement in USTelecom that the 1996 Act definitions were not
``intended to freeze in place the Commission's existing classification
of various services.'' Consistent with this approach as a traditional
tool of statutory interpretation, we reject arguments that suggest that
we should disregard this precedent largely out-of-hand. More generally,
of course, this precedent--Brand X in particular--demonstrates that the
Act does not compel a telecommunications service classification.
a. Broadband Internet Access Service Information Processing
Capabilities
11. We begin by evaluating the ``information service'' definition
and conclude that it encompasses broadband internet access service.
Broadband internet access service includes ``capabilit[ies]'' meeting
the information service definition under a range of reasonable
interpretations of that term. In other contexts, the Commission has
looked to dictionary definitions and found the term ``capability'' to
be ``broad and expansive,'' including the concepts of ``potential
ability'' and ``the capacity to be used, treated, or developed for a
particular purpose.'' Because broadband internet access service
necessarily has the capacity or potential ability to be used to engage
in the activities within the information service definition--
``generating, acquiring, storing, transforming, processing, retrieving,
utilizing, or making available information via telecommunications''--we
conclude that it is best understood to have those ``capabilit[ies].''
The record reflects that fundamental purposes of broadband internet
access service are for its use in ``generating'' and ``making
available'' information to others, for example through social media and
file sharing; ``acquiring'' and ``retrieving'' information from sources
such as websites and online streaming and audio applications, gaming
applications, and file sharing applications; ``storing'' information in
the cloud and remote servers, and via file sharing applications;
``transforming'' and ``processing'' information such as by manipulating
images and documents, online gaming use, and through applications that
offer the ability to send and receive email, cloud computing and
machine learning capabilities; and ``utilizing'' information by
interacting with stored data. These are just a few examples of how
broadband internet access service enables customers to generate,
acquire, store, transform, process, retrieve, utilize, and make
available information. These are not merely incidental uses of
broadband internet access service--rather, because it not only has
``the capacity to be used'' for these ``particular purpose[s]'' but was
designed and intended to do so, we find that broadband internet access
is best interpreted as providing customers with the ``capability'' for
such interactions with third party providers.
12. We also find that broadband internet access is an information
service irrespective of whether it provides the entirety of any end
user functionality or whether it provides end user functionality in
tandem with edge providers. We do not believe that Congress, in
focusing on the ``offering of a capability,'' intended the
classification question to turn on an analysis of which capabilities
the end user selects. Further, we are unpersuaded by commenters who
assert that in order to be considered an ``information service,'' an
ISP must not only offer customers the ``capability'' for interacting
with information that may be offered by third parties (``click-
through''), but must also provide the ultimate content and applications
themselves. Although there is no dispute that many edge providers
likewise perform functions to facilitate information processing
capabilities, they all depend on the combination of information-
processing and transmission that ISPs make available through broadband
internet access service. The fundamental purpose of broadband internet
access service is to ``enable a constant flow of computer-mediated
communications between end-user devices and various servers and routers
to facilitate interaction with online content.''
13. From the earliest decisions classifying internet access
service, the Commission recognized that even when ISPs enable
subscribers to access third party content and services, that can
constitute ``a capability for generating, acquiring, storing,
transforming, processing, retrieving, utilizing, or making available
information via telecommunications.'' As the Commission explained in
the Stevens Report, ``[s]ubscribers can retrieve files from the World
Wide Web, and browse their contents, because their service provider
offers the `capability for . . . acquiring, . . . retrieving [and]
utilizing . . . information.' '' Attempts to distinguish the
Commission's classification precedent thus are unfounded insofar as
they fail to account for this aspect of the Commission's analysis in
those orders. Thus, even where an ISP enables end-users to access the
content or applications of a third party, the Commission nonetheless
found that constituted the requisite information service
``capability.'' When the Title II Order attempted to evaluate customer
perception based on their usage of broadband internet access service,
it failed to persuasively grapple with the relevant implications of
prior Commission classification precedent. The Title II Order argued
that broadband internet access service primarily is used to access
content, applications, and services from third parties unaffiliated
with the ISP in support of the view that customers perceive it as a
separate offering of telecommunications. The Title II Order offers no
explanation as to why its narrower view of ``capability''
[[Page 7855]]
was more reasonable than the Commission's previous, long-standing view
(other than seeking to advance the classification outcome that Order
was driving towards). Consequently, the Title II Order essentially
assumed away the legal question of whether end-users perceive broadband
internet access service as offering them the ``capability for . . .
acquiring, . . . retrieving [and] utilizing . . . information'' under
the broader reading of ``capability'' in prior Commission precedent.
14. But even if ``capability'' were understood as requiring more of
the information processing to be performed by the classified service
itself, we find that broadband internet access service meets that
standard. Not only do ISPs offer end users the capability to interact
with information online in each and every one of the ways set forth
above, they also do so through a variety of functionally integrated
information processing components that are part and parcel of the
broadband internet access service offering itself. In particular, we
conclude that DNS and caching functionalities, as well as certain other
information processing capabilities offered by ISPs, are integrated
information processing capabilities offered as part of broadband
internet access service to consumers today. In addition to DNS and
caching, the record reflects that ISPs may also offer a variety of
additional features that consist of information processing
functionality inextricably intertwined with the underlying service.
These additional features include, and are not limited to: email, speed
test servers, backup and support services, geolocation-based
advertising, data storage, parental controls, unique programming
content, spam protection, pop-up blockers, instant messaging services,
on-the-go access to Wi-Fi hotspots, and various widgets, toolbars, and
applications. While we do not find the offering of these information
processing capabilities determinative of the classification of
broadband internet access service, their inclusion in the broadband
internet access service, and the capabilities and functionalities
necessary to make these features possible, further support the
``information service'' classification.
15. DNS. We find that DNS is an indispensable functionality of
broadband internet access service. While we accept that DNS is not
necessary for transmission, we reject assertions that it is not
indispensable to the broadband internet access service customers use--
and expect--today. DNS is a core function of broadband internet access
service that involves the capabilities of generating, acquiring,
storing, transforming, processing, retrieving, utilizing and making
available information. DNS is used to facilitate the information
retrieval capabilities that are inherent in internet access. DNS allows
```click through' access from one web page to another, and its computer
processing functions analyze user queries to determine which website
(and server) would respond best to the user's request.'' And
``[b]ecause it translates human language (e.g., the name of a website)
into the numerical data (i.e., an IP address) that computers can
process, it is indispensable to ordinary users as they navigate the
internet.'' Without DNS, a consumer would not be able to access a
website by typing its advertised name (e.g., fcc.gov or cnn.com). The
Brand X Court recognized the importance of DNS, concluding that ``[f]or
an internet user, `DNS is a must. . . . [N]early all of the internet's
network services use DNS. That includes the World Wide Web, electronic
mail, remote terminal access, and file transfer.' '' While ISPs are not
the sole providers of DNS services, the vast majority of ordinary
consumers rely upon the DNS functionality provided by their ISP, and
the absence of ISP-provided DNS would fundamentally change the online
experience for the consumer. We also observe that DNS, as it is used
today, provides more than a functionally integrated address-translation
capability, but also enables other capabilities critical to providing a
functional broadband internet access service to the consumer, including
for example, a variety of underlying network functionality information
associated with name service, alternative routing mechanisms, and
information distribution.
16. The treatment of similar functions in MFJ precedent bolsters
our conclusion. Despite the fact that the telecommunications management
exception (and information service definition more broadly) was drawn
most directly from the MFJ, the Title II Order essentially ignored MFJ
precedent when concluding that DNS fell within the statutory
telecommunications management exception. In addition, even the Title II
Order's limited use of Computer Inquiries precedent focused mostly on
relatively high-level Commission statements about the general sorts of
capabilities that could be basic (or adjunct-to-basic) or drew
analogies to specific holdings that are at best ambiguous as to their
application to broadband internet access service. When analyzing
``gateway'' functionalities by which BOCs would provide end-users with
access to third party information services, the MFJ court found that
``address translation,'' which enabled ``the consumer [to] use an
abbreviated code or signal . . . in order to access the information
service provider'' such as through ``the translation of a mnemonic code
into [a] telephone number,'' rendered gateways an information service.
We recognize that gateway functionalities and broadband internet access
service are not precisely coextensive in scope. We do, however, find
similarities between functionalities such as address translation and
storage and retrieval to key functionalities provided by ISPs as part
of broadband internet access service, and we conclude the court found
such gateway and similar functionalities independently sufficient to
warrant an information service classification under the MFJ. The
``address translation'' gateway function appears highly analogous to
the DNS function of broadband internet access service, which enables
end users to use easier-to-remember domain names to initiate access to
the associated IP addresses of edge providers. That MFJ precedent,
neglected by the Title II Order, thus supports our finding that the
inclusion of DNS in broadband internet access service offerings
likewise renders that service an information service. We rely on this
analogy between DNS and particular functions classified under pre-1996
Act precedent not because the technologies are identical in all
particulars, but because they share the same relevant characteristics
for purposes of making a classification decision under the Act. Given
the close fit between DNS and the address translation function
classified as an information service under the MFJ coupled with the
fact that the statutory information service definition (and
telecommunications management exception) was drawn more directly from
the MFJ, we find the MFJ precedent entitled to more weight than
analogies to Computer Inquiries precedent. We thus are not persuaded by
arguments seeking to analogize DNS to directory assistance, which the
Commission classified as ``adjunct-to-basic'' under the Computer
Inquiries.
17. We thus find that the Title II Order erred in finding that DNS
functionalities fell within the telecommunications systems management
exception to the definition of ``information service.'' That exception
from the statutory information service definition was drawn from the
language of the MFJ, and was understood as ``directed at internal
operations, not at services for
[[Page 7856]]
customers or end users.'' The court's definition of information
services excluded capabilities ``for the management, control, or
operation of a telecommunication system or the management of a
telecommunications service.'' Under the Communications Act, the
definition of ``information services'' includes an identically-worded
``telecommunications management'' exception. Commission precedent and
legislative history likewise recognize that the definition was drawn
from the MFJ. We interpret the concepts of ``management, control, or
operation'' in the telecommunications management exception consistent
with that understanding. Applying that interpretation, we find the
record reflects that little or nothing in the DNS look-up process is
designed to help an ISP ``manage'' its network; instead, DNS
functionalities ``provide stored information to end users to help them
navigate the internet.'' As AT&T explains: ``When an end user types a
domain name into his or her browser and sends a DNS query to an ISP, .
. . the ISP . . . converts the human-language domain name into a
numerical IP address, and it then conveys that information back to the
end user . . . [who] (via his or her browser) thereafter sends a
follow-up request for the internet resources located at that numerical
IP address.'' DNS does not merely ``manage'' a telecommunications
service, as some commenters assert, but rather is a function that is
useful and essential to providing internet access for the ordinary
consumer. We are persuaded that ``[w]ere DNS simply a management
function, this would not be the case.'' Comparing functions that would
fall within the exception illustrates the distinction. For example, in
contrast to DNS's interaction with users and their applications, ``non-
user, management-only protocols might include things such as Simple
Network Management Protocol (SNMP), Network Control Protocol (NETCONF),
or DOCSIS bootfiles for controlling the configuration of cable
modems.'' These protocols support services that manage the network
independent of the transmission of information initiated by a user.
Other functions that would fall into the telecommunications systems
management exception might include information systems for account
management and billing, configuration management, and the monitoring of
failures and other state information, and to keep track of which
addresses are reachable through each of the interconnected neighboring
networks.
18. The Title II Order drew erroneous conclusions from Computer
Inquiries precedent and too quickly rejected objections to its
treatment of DNS as meeting the telecommunications management
exception. The same shortcomings are present in the Title II Order's
analysis of caching, as well. Under the Computer Inquiries framework,
the Commission held that some capabilities ``may properly be associated
with basic [common carrier] service without changing its nature, or
with an enhanced service without changing the classification of the
latter as unregulated under Title II of the Act.'' These commonly came
to be known as ``adjunct'' capabilities. The Commission has held that
functions it had classified as ``adjunct-to-basic'' under the Computer
Inquiries framework will fall within the statutory telecommunications
management exception to the information service definition. Drawing
loose analogies to certain functions described as adjunct-to-basic
under Commission precedent, the Title II Order held that DNS fell
within the telecommunications management exception.
19. The Title II Order incorrectly assumed that so long as a
functionality was, in part, used in a manner that could be viewed as
adjunct-to-basic, it necessarily was adjunct-to-basic regardless of
what the functionality otherwise accomplished. In addition to the MFJ
precedent, Bureau precedent similarly has observed that adjunct-to-
basic capabilities do not include functions ``useful to end users,
rather than carriers.'' Given the lack of ambiguity in the MFJ's
holding in this regard, we find it more reasonable to interpret this
precedent to call for a similar requirement that ``adjunct to basic''
services do not include services primarily useful to end-users, and
reject arguments to the contrary. Although confronted with claims that
DNS is, in significant part, designed to be useful to end-users rather
than providers, the Title II Order nonetheless decided that it fell
within the telecommunications management exception. The same is true of
the Title II Order's treatment of caching. While conceding that DNS, as
well as other functions like caching, ``do provide a benefit to
subscribers,'' the Title II Order held that they nonetheless fell
within the telecommunications management exception because it found
some aspect of their operation also was of use to providers in managing
their networks. This expansive view of the telecommunications
management exception--and associated narrowing of the scope of
information services--is a transposition of the analytical approach
embodied in the MFJ and Computer Inquiries; under the approach in the
pre-1996 Act precedent, the analysis would instead begin with the broad
language of the information service or enhanced service definitions,
generally excluding particular functions only if the purpose served
clearly was narrowly focused on facilitating bare transmission. The
Commission and the courts made clear the narrow scope of the `adjunct-
to-basic' or `telecommunications management' categories in numerous
decisions in many different contexts.). Notably, the focus remains on
the purpose or use of the specific function in question and not merely
whether the resulting service, as a whole, is useful to end-users.
20. The Title II Order also put misplaced reliance on Computer
Inquiries adjunct-to-basic precedent from the traditional telephone
service context as a comparison when evaluating broadband internet
access service functionalities. Because broadband internet access
service was not directly addressed in pre-1996 Act Computer Inquiries
and MFJ precedent, analogies to functions that were classified under
that precedent must account for potentially distinguishing
characteristics not only in terms of technical details but also in
terms of the regulatory backdrop. The 1996 Act enunciates a policy for
the internet that distinguishes broadband internet access from legacy
services like traditional telephone service. The 1996 Act explains that
it is federal policy ``to preserve the vibrant and competitive free
market that presently exists for the internet and other interactive
computer services, unfettered by Federal or State regulation.'' The
application of potentially ambiguous precedent to broadband internet
access service should be informed by how well--or how poorly--it
advances that deregulatory statutory policy. We find that our approach
to that precedent, which results in an information service
classification of broadband internet access service, better advances
that deregulatory policy than the approach in the Title II Order, which
led to the imposition of utility-style regulation under Title II.
21. The regulatory history of traditional telephone service also
informs our understanding of Computer Inquiries precedent, further
distinguishing it from broadband internet access service. Given the
long history of common carriage offering of that service by the time of
the Computer Inquiries, it is understandable that some precedent
started with a presumption
[[Page 7857]]
that the underlying service was a ``basic service.'' But similar
assumptions would not be warranted in the case of services other than
traditional telephone service for which there was no similar
longstanding history of common carriage. Thus, not only did the Title
II Order rely on specific holdings that are at best ambiguous in their
analogy to technical characteristics of broadband internet access
service, but it failed to adequately appreciate key regulatory
distinctions between traditional telephone service and broadband
internet access service. Thus, for example, the fact that the adjunct-
to-basic classification of directory assistance arose in the
traditional telephone context likewise persuades us to give it
relatively little weight here as an analogy to DNS, and we reject
arguments to the contrary.
22. Caching. We also conclude that caching, a functionally
integrated information processing component of broadband internet
access service, provides the capability to perform functions that fall
within the information service definition. As the record reflects,
``[c]aching does much more than simply enable the user to obtain more
rapid retrieval of information through the network; caching depends on
complex algorithms to determine what information to store where and in
what format.'' This requires ``extensive information processing,
storing, retrieving, and transforming for much of the most popular
content on the internet,'' and as such, caching involves storing and
retrieving capabilities required by the ``information service''
definition. The Court affirmed this view in Brand X, finding
``reasonable'' the ``Commission's understanding'' that internet service
``facilitates access to third-party web pages by offering consumers the
ability to store, or `cache,' popular content on local computer
servers,'' which constitutes ``the `capability for . . . acquiring,
[storing] . . . retrieving [and] utilizing information.' ''
23. We find that ISP-provided caching does not merely ``manage'' an
ISP's broadband internet access service and underlying network, it
enables and enhances consumers' access to and use of information
online. The record shows that caching can be realized as part of a
service, such as DNS, which is predominantly to the benefit of the user
(DNS caching). We disagree with assertions in the record that suggest
that ISP-provided caching is not a vital part of broadband internet
access service offerings, as it may be stymied by the use of HTTPS
encryption. Caching can also be realized in terms of content that can
be accumulated by the ISP through non-confidential (i.e., non-
encrypted) retrieval of information from websites (Web caching). In
this case, the user benefits from a rapid retrieval of information from
a local cache or repository of information while the ISP benefits from
less bandwidth resources used in the retrieval of data from one or more
destinations. DNS and Web caching are functions provided as part and
parcel of the broadband internet access service. When ISPs cache
content from across the internet, they are not performing functions,
like switching, that are instrumental to pure transmission, but instead
storing third party content they select in servers in their own
networks to enhance access to information. The record reflects that
without caching, broadband internet access service would be a
significantly inferior experience for the consumer, particularly for
customers in remote areas, requiring additional time and network
capacity for retrieval of information from the internet. Thus, because
caching is useful to the consumer, we conclude that the Title II Order
erred in incorrectly categorizing caching as falling within the
telecommunications system management exception to the definition of
``information service.''
24. In addition, the Title II Order's failure to consider
applicable MFJ precedent led to mistaken analogies when it concluded
that caching fell within the statutory telecommunications management
exception. In relevant precedent, the MFJ court observed that the
information service restriction generally ``prohibits the [BOCs] from
`storing' and `retrieving' information,'' but identified ``quite
distinct settings in which storage capabilities of the [BOCs] could be
used in the information services market.'' One of the categories of
storage and retrieval identified by the court appears highly comparable
to caching. That category involved BOC provision of ``storage space in
their gateways for databases created by others'' such as ``information
service providers and end users,'' making ``communication more
efficient by moving information closer to the end user, thereby
reducing transmission costs.'' This functionality--recognized as an
information service by the MFJ court--appears highly analogous to
caching, and lends historical support to our view that the caching
functionality within broadband internet access service is best
understood as rendering broadband internet access service an
information service. The first category the court identified was ``very
short term storage,'' including, among other things, ``the basic packet
switching function,'' which ``involves the breakdown of data or voice
communications into small bits of information that are then collected
and transmitted between nodes,'' involving ``constant storage, error
checking, and retransmission, as required for accurate transmission.''
Although the court was not entirely clear, it seemed to suggest that
such functions were not information services under the MFJ. This
category appears to bear little similarity to caching, however. The
third category of ``storage and retrieval'' information service
functions identified by the court would include the BOC's provision of
``voice messaging, voice storage and retrieval, and electronic mail.''
Because that category does not appear as analogous to caching as the
category identified by the court and described above, nor was it relied
upon in the Title II Order's discussion of caching, we do not focus on
that third category in our discussion here.
25. Ignoring that MFJ precedent, the Title II Order erred in
seeking to analogize caching to `` `store and forward technology [used]
in routing messages through the network as part of a basic service' ''
mentioned in the Computer II Final Decision. In fact, consistent with
the MFJ court's identification of distinct uses of storage and
forwarding, the cited portion of the Computer II Final Decision
recognized that ``the kind of enhanced store and forward services that
can be offered are many and varied.'' In that regard, the Computer II
Final Decision distinguished ``[t]he offering of store and forward
services'' from ``store and forward technology,'' explaining that
``[m]essage or packet switching, for example, is a store and forward
technology that may be employed in providing basic service.'' Reading
that discussion in full context and in harmony with subsequent MFJ
precedent, the reference in the Computer II Final Decision to ``store
and forward technology'' appears better understood as mirroring a
category of storage and retrieval of information that the MFJ court
suggested was not an information service--in particular, ``the basic
packet switching function, . . . [which] involves the breakdown of data
or voice communications into small bits of information that are then
collected and transmitted between nodes.'' That category of activity
relied upon in the Title II Order thus actually appears to be barely or
not at all analogous to caching. We instead find more persuasive the
[[Page 7858]]
MFJ court's information service treatment of BOC provision of ``storage
space in their gateways for databases created by others'' such as
``information service providers and end users''--a distinct category of
storage and retrieval functionality that is a close fit to caching. We
are unpersuaded by claims that this MFJ precedent only is analogous to
CDNs and not ``transparent caching'' based on asserted differences in
how it is determined what content will be stored in each scenario.
Although the factual scenario discussed in the MFJ anticipated end-
users or information service providers electing what information to
store, and that fact may have partially informed the court's decision
whether to ultimately allow BOCs to provide that capability
notwithstanding its classification as an information service, we do not
read the underlying classification as turning on that issue. Further,
in addition to the distinctions between caching and store-and-forward
technology acknowledged even in this filing, Peha Dec. 7, 2017 Ex Parte
Letter at 4, we find additional shortcomings in how the Title II Order
relied on adjunct-to-basic precedent.
b. ISPs' Service Offerings Inextricably Intertwine Information
Processing Capabilities With Transmission
26. Having established that broadband internet access service has
the information processing capabilities outlined in the definition of
``information service,'' the relevant inquiry is whether ISPs'
broadband internet access service offerings make available information
processing technology inextricably intertwined with transmission. Below
we examine both how consumers perceive the offer of broadband internet
access service, as well as the nature of the service actually offered
by ISPs, and conclude that ISPs are best understood as offering a
service that inextricably intertwines the information processing
capabilities described above and transmission.
27. We begin by considering the ordinary customer's perception of
the ISP's offer of broadband internet access service. As Brand X
explained, ``[i]t is common usage to describe what a company `offers'
to a consumer as what the consumer perceives to be the integrated
finished product.'' ISPs generally market and provide information
processing capabilities and transmission capability together as a
single service. Therefore, it is not surprising that consumers perceive
the offer of broadband internet access service to include more than
mere transmission, and that customers want and pay for functionalities
that go beyond mere transmission. As Cox explains, ``[w]hile consumers
also place significant weight on obtaining a reliable and fast internet
connection, they view those attributes as a means of enabling these
capabilities to interact with information online, not as ends in and of
themselves.'' Indeed, record evidence confirms that consumers highly
value the capabilities their ISPs offer to acquire information from
websites, utilize information on the internet, retrieve such
information, and otherwise process such information. NHMC's argument,
based on what it asserts to be a representative sample of consumer
complaints filed with the Commission, is not persuasive. NHMC's
methodology relied on Natural Language Processing (NLP) to determine
words that co-occur in such complaints, and then used ``iterative
clustering algorithms'' to ``ma[p] connections among them.'' Neither
NHMC's methodology nor the representative extracts of the complaints
NHMC submitted demonstrate that individual complaints about particular
aspects of service reflect how a customer would perceive service
offerings as a whole. Indeed, the sample of complaints attached by NHMC
features a broad set of issues, ranging widely from questions about
speed to ``losing my internet connection,'' ``charg[ing] extra for your
services,'' ``interrupt[ing] the service,'' ``bully[ing] me into share
plans,'' ``Google arbitrarily engag[ing] in monopolistic practices,''
``charg[ing] me modem rental fee,'' or ``basically no technical
support.'' We further note that to the extent that perceived speed is a
common complaint, that does not mean consumers view broadband internet
access service as a pure transmission service. A consumer's perceived
speed for many activities (such as web browsing) depends on
information-processing elements of the service like DNS and caching;
indeed, caching's primary consumer benefit is allowing a more rapid
retrieval of information from a local cache (increasing the perceived
speed of a consumer's connection). Moreover, the Commission has never
relied on such complaints to identify what a service is. And for good
reason: We expect consumer complaints about problems with a service--
not every aspect of it. Indeed, applying such a methodology would lead
to absurd results: Should we redefine the public switched network based
on the millions of robocall complaints we get each year or the rural-
call-completion problems that we know are too prevalent? Of course not.
28. This view also accords with the Commission's historical
understanding that ``[e]nd users subscribing to . . . broadband
internet access service expect to receive (and pay for) a finished,
functionally integrated service that provides access to the internet.
End users do not expect to receive (or pay for) two distinct services--
both internet access service and a distinct transmission service, for
example.'' While the Title II Order dwells at length on the prominence
of transmission speed in ISP marketing, it makes no effort to compare
that emphasis to historical practice. In fact, ISPs have been
highlighting transmission speed in their marketing materials since long
before the Title II Order. The very first report on advanced
telecommunication capability pursuant to Section 706(b) of the 1996
Act, released in 1999, cited ISPs' marketing of their internet access
service speed. ISPs' inclusion of speed information in their marketing
also was acknowledged by the Court in Brand X, which nonetheless upheld
the Commission's information service classification as reasonable.
Indeed, consideration of ISP marketing practices has been part of the
backdrop of all of the Commission's decisions classifying broadband
internet access service as an information service and thus cannot
justify a departure from the historical classification of broadband
internet access service as an information service.
29. The Title II Order's reliance on ISP marketing also assumes
that it provides a complete picture of what consumers perceive as the
finished product. First, the record reflects that ISP marketing of
broadband encompasses features beyond speed and reliability. Further,
because all broadband internet access services rely on DNS and commonly
also rely on caching by ISPs, to the extent that those capabilities, in
themselves, do not provide a point of differentiation among services or
providers, it would be unsurprising that ISPs did not feature them
prominently in their marketing or advertising, particularly to
audiences already familiar with broadband internet access service
generally. Indeed, speed and reliability are not exclusive to
telecommunications services; rather, the record reflects that speed and
reliability are crucial attributes of an information service. As such,
we reject assertions that speed and reliability are only
characteristics of telecommunications services and further note that
ISPs market these aspects because they can be differentiated, unlike
DNS or caching. Consequently, the mere fact that broadband internet
access service
[[Page 7859]]
marketing often focuses on characteristics, such as transmission speed,
by which services and providers can be differentiated sheds little to
no light on whether consumers perceive broadband internet access
service as inextricably intertwining that data transmission with
information service capabilities. Neither the discussion of the
consumer's perspective by Justice Scalia nor that in the Title II Order
identifies good reasons to depart from the Commission's prior
understanding that broadband internet access is a single, integrated
information service. Justice Scalia contended that how customers
perceive cable modem service is best understood by considering the
services for which it would be a substitute--in his view at the time,
dial-up internet access and digital subscriber line (DSL) service over
telephone networks. However, dial-up internet access has substantially
diminished in marketplace significance in the subsequent years. In
addition, the legal compulsion for facilities-based carriers to offer
broadband transmission on a common carrier basis was eliminated in
2005. Fixed and mobile wireless broadband internet access service have
grown to play a much more prominent role in the broadband internet
access service marketplace, along with satellite broadband internet
access service, none of which ever was under a legal compulsion to
offer broadband transmission on a common carrier basis--nor, prior to
the Title II Order, were they interpreted as voluntarily doing so.
Consequently, whatever might have been arguable at the time of Brand X,
the service offerings in the marketplace as it developed thereafter
provide no reason to expect that consumers ``inevitabl[y]'' would view
broadband internet access service as involving ``both computing
functionality and the physical pipe'' as separate offerings based on
comparisons to the likely alternatives.
30. Separate and distinct from our finding that an ISP ``offers''
an information service from the consumer's perspective, we find that as
a factual matter, ISPs offer a single, inextricably intertwined
information service. The record reflects that information processes
must be combined with transmission in order for broadband internet
access service to work, and it is the combined information processing
capabilities and transmission functions that an ISP offers with
broadband internet access service. Thus, even assuming that any
individual consumer could perceive an ISP's offer of broadband internet
access service as akin to a bare transmission service, the information
processing capabilities that are actually offered as an integral part
of the service make broadband internet access service an information
service as defined by the Act. As such, we reject commenters'
assertions that the primary function of ISPs is to simply transfer
packets and not process information.
31. The inquiry called for by the relevant classification precedent
focuses on the nature of the service offering the provider makes,
rather than being limited to the functions within that offering that
particular subscribers do, in fact, use or that third parties also
provide. As the Commission recognized in the Cable Modem Order,
internet access service was appropriately classified as an offering of
the capabilities with the definition of an information service
``regardless of whether subscribers use all of the functions provided
as part of the service.'' The Title II Order erroneously contended
that, because functions like DNS and caching potentially could be
provided by entities other than the ISP itself, those functions should
not be understood as part of a single, integrated information service
offered by ISPs. However, the fact that some consumers obtain these
functionalities from third-party alternatives is not a basis for
ignoring the capabilities that a broadband provider actually
``offers.'' The Title II Order gave no meaningful explanation why a
contrary, narrower interpretation of ``offer'' was warranted other
than, implicitly, its seemingly end-results driven effort to justify a
telecommunications service classification of broadband internet access
service.
32. Our findings today are consistent with classification precedent
prior to the Title II Order, which consistently found that ISPs offer a
single, integrated service. Although we find the pre-1996 Act
classification precedent relevant to our classification of broadband
internet access service, we reject the view that Congress would have
expected classification under the 1996 Act's statutory definitions to
be tied to the substantive common carrier transmission requirements
imposed under those frameworks. We conclude that the best view of the
text and structure of the Act undercuts arguments that Congress sought
to preserve the substance of pre-1996 Act regulations through the
definitions it adopted. Instead, where Congress sought to address
substantive requirements akin to those in the MFJ and Computer
Inquiries, it did so by adopting subjective obligations in the 1996
Act--even if not identical to the pre-1996 Act requirements--and
subject to their own Congressionally specified standards for when and
to what entities they apply. In addition, the wholesale service focus
of substantive MFJ and Computer Inquiries common carrier transmission
obligations also distinguishes them from the retail service we classify
here, likewise undermining any claimed relevance of those pre-1996 Act
transmission requirements to our classification decision. The
Commission recognized, for example, that the transmission underlying
broadband internet access required by the Computer Inquiries to be
offered on an unbundled, common carrier basis and provided to ISPs was
not a ``retail'' service within the meaning of Section 251(c)(4) resale
requirements. Nor did such a common carrier transmission service itself
enable access to the internet, even if purchased by end-users. By
comparison, under the Computer Inquiries, the finished service offered
to end-users relying on the required common carrier transmission as an
input was regulated as an enhanced service, not a common carrier
offering, even when offered by the facilities-based carrier's
subsidiary. Given our focus here on the finished retail broadband
internet access service, we see little relevance to prior regulatory
requirements that were imposed to ensure competing providers had access
to a wholesale input in the form of a compelled common carriage
offering of bare transmission that did not itself provide internet
access. Even the early classification analysis in the Stevens Report
recognized that ``[i]n offering service to end users'' ISPs ``do more
than resell [ ] data transport services. They conjoin the data
transport with data processing, information provision, and other
computer-mediated offerings, thereby creating an information service.''
In Brand X, the Court rejected claims that ``[w]hen a consumer . . .
accesses content provided by parties other than the cable company''
that ``consumer uses `pure transmission.' '' Subsequent Commission
decisions involving other forms of broadband internet access likewise
all concluded that the broadband internet access service was a single,
integrated service that did not involve a stand-alone offering of
telecommunications. Although parties have, over time, held various
views regarding the proper classification of broadband internet access
services, the mere fact that a party held such a view in the past, or
holds such a view today, does not render a Commission decision
confirming a particular view ``moot,''
[[Page 7860]]
since a private party's subjective view is not authoritative. The Court
further found that ``the high-speed transmission used to provide cable
modem service is a functionally integrated component of that service
because it transmits data only in connection with the further
processing of information and is necessary to provide internet
service.'' This distinction makes broadband internet access service
fundamentally different than standard telephone service, which the
Supreme Court noted does not become an ``information service'' merely
because its transmission service may be ``trivially affected'' by some
additional capability such as voicemail. Where the addition of some
further capability has appeared to have only a trivial effect on the
nature of a service, the Commission has previously declined requests
for reclassification. Due to the functionally integrated nature of
broadband internet access service, however, we reject claims that those
decisions call for a different approach than we adopt here. Likewise,
the outcome in the Bureau-level Cisco WebEx Order accords with our
approach, given the finding that the information service capabilities
more than trivially affected the transmission capability in the
scenario addressed there. Contrary to some arguments, the Bureau had no
need to--and did not--address the classification of other service
scenarios, and we reject arguments for a different classification
approach that are premised on assumptions about how those unaddressed
scenarios would have been analyzed or classified. The core, essential
elements of these prior analyses of the functional nature of internet
access remain persuasive as to broadband internet access service today.
We adhere to that view notwithstanding arguments that some subset of
the array of internet access uses identified in the Stevens Report or
subsequent decisions either are no longer as commonly used, or occur
more frequently today. Even at the time of the Cable Modem Order the
Commission recognized the role of user-generated content, and its
decision in no way hinged on distinctions in how retail customers of
cable modem service used that service in that respect.
33. We disagree with commenters who assert that ISPs necessarily
offer both an information service and a telecommunications service
because broadband internet access service includes a transmission
component. In providing broadband internet access service, an ISP makes
use of telecommunications--i.e., it provides information-processing
capabilities ``via telecommunications''--but does not separately offer
telecommunications on a stand-alone basis to the public. By definition,
all information services accomplish their functions ``via
telecommunications,'' and as such, broadband internet access service
has always had a telecommunications component intrinsically intertwined
with the computer processing, information provision, and computer
interactivity capabilities an information service offers. We observe
that placing information in IP packets does not change the form of
information. We find that the transmission of IP packets is
transmission of the user's choosing, and also agree that ``[c]hanging
the packet structure of an IP packet from IPv4 to IPv6'' does not
change the form of the information. As just one example, in support of
its classification decision, the Title II Order notes that it is
technically possible for a transmission component underlying broadband
internet access service to be separated out and offered on a common
carrier basis. The same would be equally true of many information
services, however, given that the information service capabilities are,
by definition, available ``via telecommunications.'' Indeed, service
providers, who are in the best position to understand the inputs used
in broadband internet access service, do not appear to dispute that the
``via telecommunications'' criteria is satisfied even if also arguing
that they are not providing telecommunications to end-users. For
example, ISPs typically transmit traffic between aggregation points on
their network and the ISPs' connections with other networks. Whether
self-provided by the ISP or purchased from a third party, that readily
appears to be transmission between or among points selected by the ISP
of traffic that the ISP has chosen to have carried by that transmission
link. We reject as overbroad the claim that ``a transmission is
`telecommunications' within the meaning of 47 U.S.C. 153(30) only if
the transmission is capable of communicating with all circuit switched
devices on the PSTN or has the purpose of facilitating the use of the
PSTN without altering its fundamental character as a telephone
network.'' This claim appears premised on incorporating Section 332's
definition of a commercial mobile service (which must be
``interconnected'' with the ``public switched network'') into Section 3
of the Act and drawing from pre-1996 Act precedent using an end-to-end
analysis to determine the regulatory jurisdiction of communications
traffic to inform the interpretation of the term ``points.'' But we
find no evidence in the text of the statute that Congress intended to
import the commercial mobile service definition from one section into
another, and our precedent similarly does not countenance such an
importation. Nor is the end-to-end analysis the only pre-1996 Act
precedent from which the concept of ``points'' in the
``telecommunications'' definition might have been drawn so as to
unambiguously foreclose our conclusion that ``via telecommunications''
is satisfied here. Such inclusion of a transmission component does not
render broadband internet access services telecommunications services;
if it did, the entire category of information services would be
narrowed drastically. Because we find it more reasonable to conclude
that at least some telecommunications is being used as an input into
broadband internet access service--thereby satisfying the ``via
telecommunications'' criteria--we need not further address the scope of
the ``telecommunications'' definition in order to justify our
classification of broadband internet access service as an information
service. We thus do not comprehensively address other criticisms of the
Title II Order's interpretation and applications of the
``telecommunications'' definition, which potentially could have
implications beyond the scope of issues we are considering in this
proceeding.
34. The approach we adopt today best implements the Commission's
long-standing view that Congress intended the definitions of
``telecommunications service'' and ``information service'' to be
mutually exclusive ways to classify a given service. As the Brand X
Court found, the term ``offering'' in the telecommunications service
definition ``can reasonably be read to mean a `stand-alone' offering of
telecommunications.'' Where, as in the case of broadband internet
access services, a service involving transmission inextricably
intertwines that transmission with information service capabilities--in
the form of an integrated information service--there cannot be ``a
`stand-alone' offering of telecommunications'' as required under that
interpretation of the telecommunications service definition. This
conclusion is true even if the information service could be said to
involve the provision of telecommunications as a component of the
service. The Commission's historical approach to internet access
services carefully navigated that issue, while the Title II Order, by
contrast, threatened to
[[Page 7861]]
usher in a much more sweeping scope of ``telecommunications services.''
35. The Title II Order interpretation stands in stark contrast to
the Commission's historical classification precedent and the views of
all Justices in Brand X. Beginning with the earliest classification
decisions, the Commission found that transmission provided by ISPs
outside the last mile was part of an integrated information service.
The DSL transmission service previously required to be unbundled by the
Computer Inquiries rules likewise was limited to the ``last mile''
connection between the end-user and the ISP. Nor did any Justice in
Brand X contest the view that, beyond the last mile, cable operators
were offering an information service. Indeed, the Title II Order's
broad interpretation of ``telecommunications service'' stands in
contrast to the views of Justice Scalia himself, on which the Title II
Order purports to rely. Justice Scalia was skeptical that a
telecommunications service classification of cable modem service would
lead to the classification of ISPs as telecommunications carriers based
on the transmission underlying their ``connect[ions] to other parts of
the internet, including internet backbone providers.'' Yet the Title II
Order reached essentially that outcome. The Title II Order's
interpretation of the statutory definitions did not merely lead it to
classify ``last mile'' transmission as a telecommunications service.
Rather, under the view of the Title II Order, even the transmissions
underlying an ISP's connections to other parts of the internet,
including internet backbone providers, were part of the classified
telecommunications service. Even if the Title II Order's classification
approach does not technically render the category of information
services a nullity, the fact that its view of telecommunications
services sweeps so much more broadly than previously considered
possible provides significant support for our reading of the statute
and the classification decision we make today. That the Commission
previously identified policy concerns about internet traffic exchange
says nothing about classification, and thus is not to the contrary. Nor
did the Advanced Services proceedings identify interconnection
obligations on providers of xDSL transmission as services necessary to
ensure the provision of internet access. Instead, any interconnection
obligations identified there were limited to interconnection between
providers of common carrier xDSL transmission service and other
telecommunications carriers (rather than providers of edge services or
non-common carrier backbone services). The cited portion of the
Advanced Services Remand Order does not even have anything to do with
interconnection requirements or the scope of functions in an xDSL-based
advanced service. Rather, it analyzed the jurisdiction of the traffic
being carried over the service, which, under the traditional end-to-end
analysis, was not limited in scope to any given service within a
broader communications pathway.
36. In contrast, our approach leaves ample room for a meaningful
range of ``telecommunications services.'' Historically, the Commission
has distinguished service offerings that ``always and necessarily
combine'' functions such as ``computer processing, information
provision, and computer interactivity with data transport, enabling end
users to run a variety of applications such as email, and access web
pages and newsgroups,'' on the one hand, from services ``that carriers
and end users typically use [ ] for basic transmission purposes'' on
the other hand. Our interpretation thus stops far short of the view
that ``every transmission of information becomes an information
service.'' Thus, an offering like broadband internet access service
that ``always and necessarily'' includes integrated transmission and
information service capabilities would be an information service. The
distinction between services that ``always and necessarily'' include
integrated transmission and information service capabilities and those
that do not also highlights a critical difference between internet
access service and the service addressed in precedent such as the
Advanced Services Order. The transmission underlying internet access
service that, prior to the Wireline Broadband Classification Order,
carriers had been required by the Computer Inquiries to unbundle and
offer as a bare transmission service on a common carrier basis to
ensure its availability to competing enhanced service providers--and
which did not itself provide internet access--is another specific
example of a service that does not ``always and necessarily'' include
integrated transmission and information service capabilities. The
Commission naturally recognized at the time that the compelled common
carriage offering of bare transmission was a telecommunications
service, and we reject the view that such an acknowledgment is
inconsistent with, or undercuts our reliance on, precedent classifying
internet access service as an integrated information service. In
addition, the discussion of xDSL advanced services in the Advanced
Services Order cited by commenters addressed the transmission service
generally. It did not purport to be focused specifically on the use of
xDSL transmission in connection with internet access service, rather
than addressing the classification of the stand-alone transmission
service as a general matter. The Commission's historical interpretation
thus gives full meaning to both ``information service'' and
``telecommunications service'' categories in the Act.
37. We reject assertions that the analysis we adopt today would
necessarily mean that standard telephone service is likewise an
information service. The record reflects that broadband internet access
service is categorically different from standard telephone service in
that it is ``designed with advanced features, protocols, and security
measures so that it can integrate directly into electronic computer
systems and enable users to electronically create, retrieve, modify and
otherwise manipulate information stored on servers around the world.''
Further, ``[t]he dynamic network functionality enabling the internet
connectivity provided by [broadband internet access services] is
fundamentally different from the largely static one dimensional,
transmission oriented Time Division Multiplexing (TDM) voice network.''
This finding is consistent with past distinctions. Under pre-1996 Act
MFJ precedent, for example, although the provision of time and weather
services was an information service, when a BOC's traditional telephone
service was used to call a third party time and weather service ``the
Operating Company does not `provide information services' within the
meaning of section II(D) of the decree; it merely transmits a call
under the tariff.'' In other words, the fundamental nature of
traditional telephone service, and the commonly-understood purpose for
which traditional telephone service is designed and offered, is to
provide basic transmission--a fact not changed by its incidental use,
on occasion, to access information services. By contrast, the
fundamental nature of broadband internet access service, and the
commonly-understood purpose for which broadband internet access service
is designed and offered, is to enable customers to generate, acquire,
store, transform, process, retrieve, utilize, and make available
information. In addition, broadband internet access service
[[Page 7862]]
includes DNS and caching functionalities, as well as certain other
information processing capabilities. As such, we reject assertions
that, under the approach we adopt today, any telephone service would be
an information service because voice customers can get access to either
automated information services or a live person who can provide
information.
38. Additionally, efforts to treat the Stevens Report as an outlier
that should not have been followed in subsequent classification
decisions--and should not be followed here--are ultimately
unpersuasive. The clear recognition in the Stevens Report that the ISPs
at issue were themselves providing data transmission as part of their
offerings undercuts arguments seeking to distinguish the Stevens Report
based on the theory that the transmission used to connect to ISPs
typically involved common carrier services either directly (via a call
to a dial-up ISP using traditional telephone service) or indirectly
(with the ISP using common carrier broadband transmission as a
wholesale input into its retail information service). While the extent
of data transmission provided by the ISPs that were found to be
offering information services in the Stevens Report might be
incrementally less than the transmission provided by the ISPs dealt
with in subsequent information service classification decisions, that
appears to be at most a difference in degree, rather than a difference
in kind, and the record does not demonstrate otherwise. Nor can the
Stevens Report's analysis and information service classification be
distinguished on the grounds that the ISPs there generally did not own
the facilities they used. Although the Stevens Report observed that the
analysis of whether a single integrated service was being offered was
``more complicated when it comes to offerings by facilities-based
providers,'' it did not prejudge the resolution of that question. Thus,
there is no reason to simply assume that it was inappropriate for the
Commission to build upon the Stevens Report precedent when analyzing
service offerings from facilities-based providers beginning in the
Cable Modem Order. Nor do commenters identify material technical
differences when facilities ownership is involved that would mandate a
different classification analysis. While the Stevens Report recognized
that under Computer Inquires precedent ``offerings by non-facilities-
based providers combining communications and computing components
should always be deemed enhanced,'' had its analysis simply been
carrying forward that approach most of its analysis would have been
unnecessary (since internet access clearly did combine communications
and computing components). Thus, whether or not the more extensive
analysis set forth in the Stevens Report was necessary to find internet
access provided by non-facilities-based ISPs to be an information
service, that analysis cannot be said to be a mere relic of the
Computer Inquiries approach to non-facilities based providers. Finally,
our reliance on classification precedent does not rest on the Stevens
Report alone, but draws from the full range of classification
precedent, both pre- and post-1996 Act. This reliance notably includes
not only the Commission's classification decisions, but the Supreme
Court's subsequent analysis in Brand X. And although some commenters
criticize the lack of express consideration of the possible application
of the telecommunications management exception in the Stevens Report,
our evaluation of the pre-1996 Act MFJ and Computer Inquiries precedent
better accords with outcome of that Report and the subsequent
classification decisions than it does with the Title II Order in that
regard. We reject similar criticisms of other precedent for the same
reason.
3. Other Provisions of the Act Support Broadband's Information Service
Classification
39. We also find that other provisions of the Act support our
conclusion that broadband internet access service is best classified as
an information service. We do not assert that the language in Sections
230 and 231 is determinative of the information service classification;
rather, we find it to be supportive of our analysis of the textual
provisions at issue. As such, we find Public Knowledge's assertions
that the Commission's reasoning ``would overrule the Supreme Court's
holding in Brand X . . . [in which] the Court ruled that the
Communications Act does not make explicit the correct classification of
BIAS'' inapposite. For instance, Congress codified its view in Section
230(b)(2) of the Act, stating that it is the policy of the United
States ``to preserve the vibrant and competitive free market that
presently exists for the internet and other interactive computer
services, unfettered by Federal or State regulation.'' This statement
confirms that the free market approach that flows from classification
as an information service is consistent with Congress's intent. In
contrast, we find it hard to reconcile this statement in Section
230(b)(2) with a conclusion that Congress intended the Commission to
subject broadband internet access service to common carrier regulation
under Title II.
40. Additional provisions within Sections 230 and 231 of the Act
lend further support to our interpretation. Section 230(f)(2) defines
an interactive computer service to mean ``any information service,
system, or access software provider that provides or enables computer
access by multiple users to a computer server, including specifically a
service or system that provides access to the Internet and such systems
operated or services offered by libraries or educational
institutions.'' Thus, on its face, the plain language of this provision
appears to reflect Congress' judgment that internet access service is
an information service.
41. Section 230 states that an ``information service'' includes ``a
service or system that provides access to the internet,'' and we
disagree with commenters who read the definition of ``interactive
computer service'' differently. Specifically, we disagree with
commenters asserting that it is unclear whether the clause ``including
specifically a service . . . that provides access to the internet''
modifies ``information service'' or some other noun phrase, such as
``access software provider'' or ``system.'' We think it a more
reasonable interpretation that the phrase ``service . . . that provides
access to the internet'' modifies the noun phrase ``information
service.'' Similarly, we disagree that Section 230(f)(2) proves only
``that there exist information services that provide access to the
internet, not that all services that provide access to the internet are
information services.'' On the contrary, we agree with AT&T that ``the
formula `any X, including specifically a Y,' does logically imply that
all Ys are Xs.''
42. Reliance on Section 230(f)(2) to inform the Commission's
interpretations and applications of Titles I and II accords with widely
accepted canons of statutory interpretation. The Supreme Court has
recognized there is a ``natural presumption that identical words used
in different parts of the same act are intended to have the same
meaning.'' And there is nothing in the context of either section that
overcomes the presumption. Indeed, the similarity of circumstances
confirms the presumption of similar meaning, as the deregulatory
approach to information services embodied in Titles I and II, as well
as the deregulatory policy of Section 230, were all adopted as part of
the 1996 Act. Thus, we disagree with the Title II Order's argument that
giving
[[Page 7863]]
Section 230 its plain meaning would be ``an oblique'' way to ``settle
the regulatory status of broadband internet access.'' On the contrary,
we agree that ``it is hardly `oblique' for Congress to confirm in
Section 230 that internet access should be classified as an unregulated
information service when elsewhere in the same legislation Congress
codifies a definition of `information services' that was long
understood to include gateway services such as internet access.'' And
while the USTelecom court did not find this definition determinative on
the issue, we find that ``it is nonetheless a strong indicator that
Congress was more comfortable with the prevailing view that provision
of internet access is not a telecommunications service, and should not
be subject to the array of Title II statutory provisions.'' We find
inapplicable the USTelecom court's invocation of the principle that
``Congress . . . does not alter the fundamental details of a regulatory
scheme in vague terms or ancillary provisions.'' Section 230 did not
alter any fundamental details of Congress's regulatory scheme but was
part and parcel of that scheme, and confirmed what follows from a plain
reading of Title I--namely, that broadband internet access service
meets the definition of an information service. The legislative history
of Section 230 also lends support to the view that Congress did not
intend the Commission to subject broadband internet access service to
Title II regulation. The congressional record reflects that the
drafters of Section 230 did ``not wish to have a Federal Computer
Commission with an army of bureaucrats regulating the internet.'' We
likewise reject arguments premised on the theory that we are treating
definitions in Section 230 and 231 as dispositive, rather than relying
on them to inform our understanding of Congress' intent as revealed by
the text and structure of the Act more broadly.
43. Section 231, inserted into the Communications Act a year after
the 1996 Act's passage, similarly lends support to our conclusion that
broadband internet access service is an information service. It
expressly states that ``internet access service'' ``does not include
telecommunications services,'' but rather ``means a service that
enables users to access content, information, electronic mail, or other
services offered over the internet, and may also include access to
proprietary content, information, and other services as part of a
package of services offered to consumers.'' Further, the carve-outs in
Section 231(b)(1)-(2) differentiate the provision of telecommunications
services and the provision of internet access service. It is hard to
imagine clearer statutory language. The Commission has consistently
held that categories of telecommunications service and information
service are mutually exclusive; thus, because it is an information
service, internet access cannot be a telecommunications service. Our
interpretation of ``telecommunications service'' and ``information
service'' as mutually exclusive ways to classify a given service thus
demonstrates the relevance of Section 231 notwithstanding that it does
not expressly define broadband internet access service as an
information service. On its face then, this language strongly supports
our conclusion that, under the best reading of the statute, broadband
internet access service is an information service, not a
telecommunications service. Nothing in the text of Section 231 reveals
that the use of ``internet access service'' there is limited to dial-up
internet access. To the contrary, it would seem anomalous for Congress
only to exempt entities providing dial-up internet access and not other
forms of internet access from the prohibitions of Section 231(a). We
thus are unpersuaded by arguments advocating a narrower interpretation
of ``internet access service'' in Section 231.
44. We also find that the purposes of the 1996 Act are better
served by classifying broadband internet access service as an
information service. Congress passed the Telecommunications Act to
``promote competition and reduce regulation.'' Further, as a bipartisan
group of Senators stated, ``[n]othing in the 1996 Act or its
legislative history suggests that Congress intended to alter the
current classification of internet and other information services or to
expand traditional telephone regulation to new and advanced services.''
Or as Senator John McCain put it, ``[i]t certainly was not Congress's
intent in enacting the supposedly pro-competitive, deregulatory 1996
Act to extend the burdens of current Title II regulation to internet
services, which historically have been excluded from regulation.'' It
stands these goals on their head for the Commission, as deployment of
advanced services reaches the mainstream of Americans' lives, to
perpetuate the very Title II regulatory edifice that the 1996 Act
sought to dismantle. An information service classification will
``reduce regulation'' and preserve a free market ``unfettered by
Federal or State regulation.''
45. Finally, we observe that the structure of Title II appears to
be a poor fit for broadband internet access service. Indeed, numerous
Title II provisions explicitly assume that all telecommunications
services are a telephone service. For example, Section 221 addresses
special provisions related to telephone companies, Section 251
addresses the obligations of local exchange carriers and incumbent
local exchange carriers, and Section 271 addresses limitations on Bell
Operating Companies' provision of interLATA services. For example, to
obtain authority to offer in-region interLATA services, the BOCs have
to offer a number of functions of particular relevance to the provision
of telephone service. Therefore, it is no surprise that the Title II
Order found that many provisions of Title II were ill-suited to
broadband internet access services, and the Commission was forced to,
on its own motion, forbear either in whole or in part on a permanent or
temporary basis from 30 separate sections of Title II as well as from
other provisions of the Act and Commission rules. We find that the
significant forbearance the Commission deemed necessary in the Title II
Order strongly suggests that the regulatory framework of Title II,
which was specifically designed to regulate telephone services, is
unsuited for the dissimilar and dynamic broadband internet access
service marketplace.
B. Reinstating the Private Mobile Service Classification of Mobile
Broadband Internet Access Service
46. Having determined that broadband internet access service,
regardless of whether offered using fixed or mobile technologies, is an
information service under the Act, we now address the appropriate
classification of mobile broadband internet access service under
Section 332 of the Act. We restore the prior longstanding definitions
and interpretation of this section and conclude that mobile broadband
internet access service should not be classified as a commercial mobile
service or its functional equivalent.
47. Background. Section 332 of Title III, enacted by Congress as
part of the Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act of 1993 (the Budget Act),
provides a specific framework that applies to providers of ``commercial
mobile service.'' The section defines ``commercial mobile service'' as:
``any mobile service . . . that is provided for profit and makes
interconnected service available (A) to the public or (B) to such
classes of eligible users as to be effectively available to a
substantial portion of the public, as specified by regulation by the
Commission.''
[[Page 7864]]
``Interconnected service,'' in turn, is defined as ``service that is
interconnected with the public switched network (as such terms are
defined by regulation by the Commission).'' In 1994, the Commission
adopted regulations implementing this section, codifying the definition
of ``commercial mobile service'' under the term ``commercial mobile
radio service'' (CMRS). Looking at the statute's text, structure,
legislative history, and purpose, the Commission defined the ``public
switched network'' as ``[a]ny common carrier switched network, whether
by wire or radio, including local exchange carriers, interexchange
carriers, and mobile service providers, that use[s] the North American
Numbering Plan in connection with the provision of switched services.''
It defined ``interconnected service'' as ``a service that gives
subscribers the capability to communicate . . . [with] all other users
on the public switched network.''
48. Section 332 distinguishes commercial mobile service from
``private mobile service,'' defined as ``any mobile service . . . that
is not a commercial mobile service or the functional equivalent of a
commercial mobile service, as specified by regulation by the
Commission.'' In 1994, the Commission established its functional
equivalence test, which starts with a presumption that ``a mobile
service that does not meet the definition of CMRS is a private mobile
radio service.'' Overcoming this presumption requires an analysis of a
variety of factors to determine whether the mobile service in question
is the functional equivalent of commercial mobile service, including
``consumer demand for the service to determine whether the service is
closely substitutable for a commercial mobile radio service; whether
changes in price for the service under examination, or for the
comparable commercial mobile radio service would prompt customers to
change from one service to the other; and market research information
identifying the targeted market for the service under review.''
Emphasizing the high bar it had set, the Commission expected that
``very few mobile services that do not meet the definition of CMRS will
be a close substitute for a commercial mobile radio service.'' We note
that, in another Order adopted today, we are recodifying these factors
under Section 20.3 of the Commission's rules, but not modifying their
substance.
49. The Act treats providers of commercial mobile service as common
carriers, and the legislative history of the 1996 Act suggests that
Congress intended the definition of ``telecommunications service'' to
include commercial mobile service. In contrast, the Act prohibits the
Commission from treating providers of private mobile service as common
carriers.
50. In 2007, the Commission found that wireless broadband internet
access service was not a commercial mobile service because it did not
meet the definition of an ``interconnected service'' under the Act and
the Commission's rules. It found that wireless broadband internet
access was not ``interconnected'' with the ``public switched network''
because it did not use the North American Numbering Plan, which limited
``subscribers' ability to communicate to or receive communication from
all users in the public switched network.'' The Commission concluded
that Section 332 and the Commission's rules ``did not contemplate
wireless broadband internet access service as provided today'' and that
a commercial mobile service ``must still be interconnected with the
local exchange or interexchange switched network as it evolves.''
51. In the Title II Order, the Commission reversed course. First,
the Commission changed definitions of two key terms within the
definition of commercial mobile service. It broadened the definition of
the term ``public switched network'' to include services that use
``public IP addresses.'' And it redefined the term ``interconnected
service'' by deleting the word ``all'' from the requirement that the
service give subscribers the capability to communicate with ``all other
users on the public switched network,'' so that a service would be
interconnected even if users of such a service could not communicate
with all other users. By manipulating these definitions, the Commission
engineered a conclusion that mobile broadband internet access was
interconnected with the public switched network and was an
interconnected service under Section 332.
52. Second, the Title II Order found that even if it had not
changed the definitions, it could change the scope of the service to
meet them. Specifically, the Commission found that ``users have the
`capability' . . . to communicate with NANP numbers using their
broadband connection through the use of VoIP applications.''
Accordingly it found that, by including services not offered by the
mobile broadband internet access service provider as part of the
service, mobile broadband internet access service would now meet the
regulatory definition of ``interconnected service'' adopted in 1994.
53. Third, the Title II Order eschewed the functional equivalence
test contained in the Commission's rules to find that mobile broadband
internet access service was functionally equivalent to commercial
mobile service. Rather than apply that test, the Commission reasoned
that the two were functionally equivalent because ``like commercial
mobile service, [mobile broadband internet access service] is a widely
available, for profit mobile service that offers mobile subscribers the
capability to send and receive communications on their mobile device to
and from the public.''
54. In the Internet Freedom Notice of Proposed Rulemaking (NPRM)
(82 FR 25568), the Commission proposed to ``restore the meaning of
`public switched network' under Section 332(d)(2) to its pre-Title II
Order focus on the traditional public switched telephone network'' and
``to return to our prior definition of `interconnected service.' '' The
Commission further proposed to return to the analysis of the Wireless
Broadband Internet Access Order and find that mobile broadband internet
access service was a private mobile service. Finally, it proposed to
reconsider the Title II Order's departure from the functional
equivalence test codified in our rules.
55. Discussion. We find that the definitions of the terms ``public
switched network'' and ``interconnected service'' that the Commission
adopted in the 1994 Second CMRS Report and Order reflect the best
reading of the Act, and accordingly, we readopt the earlier
definitions. We further find that, under these definitions, mobile
broadband internet access service is not a commercial mobile service.
56. We find that the Commission's original interpretation of
``public switched network'' was more consistent with the ordinary
meaning and commonly understood definition of the term and with
Commission precedent. On multiple prior occasions before Section
332(d)(2) was enacted, the Commission used the term ``public switched
network'' to refer to the traditional public switched telephone
network. In 1981, for example, the Commission noted that ``the public
switched network interconnects all telephones in the country.'' In
1992, the Commission described its cellular service policy as
``encourag[ing] the creation of a nationwide, seamless system,
interconnected with the public switched network so that cellular and
landline telephone customers can
[[Page 7865]]
communicate with each other on a universal basis.'' Courts also used
the term ``public switched network'' when referring to the traditional
telephone network. Based on this history of usage of the term, the
Commission, in 1994, tied its definition of the term ``public switched
network'' to the traditional switched telephone network. We find this
approach appropriately reflects the fundamental canon of statutory
construction that ``unless otherwise defined, words will be interpreted
as taking their ordinary, contemporary, common meaning.'' We find that
the legislative history of the Budget Act further supports this view.
One commenter notes that the Budget Act conferees chose the Senate
version of the relevant statutory definitions, including the use of the
term ``public switched network,'' over the House version, which used
the term ``public switched telephone network,'' and argues that
Congress thereby rejected the latter term. We note, however, that the
conferees also expressly identified the substantive differences between
the House and Senate versions of the definitions, and notably absent
from their list was any contrast between the Senate's use of ``public
switched network'' and the House's use of ``public switched telephone
network,'' suggesting that the conferees did not view the two terms as
a significant difference.
57. We also find that the Commission's prior interpretation is more
consistent with the text of Section 332(d)(2), in which Congress
provided that commercial mobile service must provide a service that is
interconnected with ``the public switched network.'' We find that the
use of the definite article ``the'' and singular term ``network'' shows
that Congress intended ``public switched network'' to mean a single,
integrated network. We therefore agree with commenters who argue that
it was not meant to encompass multiple networks whose users cannot
necessarily communicate or receive communications across networks.
Consistent with Congress's directive to define ``the public switched
network,'' the restored definition reflects that the public switched
network is a singular network that ``must still be interconnected with
the local exchange or interexchange switched network as it evolves,''
as opposed to multiple networks that need not be connected to the
public telephone network. That the Commission's original interpretation
better reflects Congressional intent is further evidenced by the fact
that, although Congress has amended the Communications Act and Section
332 on multiple occasions since the Commission defined the term, it has
never changed the Commission's interpretation. As we further discuss
elsewhere in connection with the term ``interconnected service,'' we
find the best interpretation is to classify a service under Section 332
based solely on the nature of the service offered. Even if we were to
consider such applications, however, we find that the public switched
telephone network and the internet are and will continue to be distinct
and separate networks, and cannot be considered a singular, integrated
network as intended by the term ``the public switched network.'' The
deployment of the Internet of Things (IoT), for example, will mean a
dramatic increase in the number of non-VoIP-capable end-points, such as
IP-enabled televisions, washing machines, and thermostats, and other
smart devices.
58. We also restore the definition of ``interconnected service''
that existed prior to the Title II Order. Prior to that Order, the term
was defined under the Commission's rules as a service ``that gives
subscribers the capability to communicate to or receive communication
from all other users on the public switched network.'' The Title II
Order modified this definition by deleting the word ``all,'' finding
that mobile broadband internet access service should still be
considered an interconnected service even if it only enabled users to
communicate with ``some'' other users of the public switched network
rather than all. We agree with commenters who argue that the best
reading of ``interconnected service'' is one that enables communication
between its users and all other users of the public switched network.
This reading ensures that the public switched network remains the
single, integrated network that we find Congress intended in Section
332(d)(2), as reflected in the statutory definition of ``interconnected
service'' as one that is interconnected with ``the public switched
network.'' The Title II Order rejected this reading on the ground that
the Commission has previously recognized that interconnected services
may be limited in certain ways. While an interconnected service is
required to provide its users with the capability to communicate with
or receive communication from all other users of the public switched
network, the Commission has permitted an interconnected service to
restrict access to the public switched network in certain limited ways
(such as the blocking of 900 numbers). This limited exception to
general access has existed since the original definition of the term
``interconnected service'' was adopted, and the record does not
demonstrate that it has caused confusion or misunderstandings about
what services may be considered interconnected. Accordingly, we will
continue to apply the definition of ``interconnected service'' in this
fashion, and we see no need to codify any language further clarifying
the exception. We agree with Verizon, however, that ``[t]here is a
massive difference between limited, targeted restrictions that deny
access to certain points on the network and the situation envisioned by
the Title II Order, where millions of users on what is ostensibly the
same network are incapable of reaching each other.''
59. Some commenters who argue that the Title II Order's revised
definitions should be maintained point to Congress's delegation of
interpretational authority to the Commission and the Commission's
previous position that it could define the public switched network
based on new technology and consumer demand. In defining the terms
``public switched network'' and ``interconnected service'' in the
Second CMRS Report and Order, however, the Commission recognized that
commercial mobile service must still be interconnected with the local
exchange or interexchange switched network, and it stated that ``any
switched common carrier service that is interconnected with the
traditional local exchange or interexchange switched network will be
defined as part of that network for purposes of our definition of
`commercial mobile radio services.' '' We disagree with commenters
arguing that, by not including IP addresses in the definition of the
public switched network, the Commission would be failing to recognize
the evolution of mobile network technologies that have blurred the
lines between circuit switched and packet switched networks. The
Commission's original decision properly reflects that the public
switched network should not be defined in a static way and should
reflect that the public switched network is continuously growing and
changing, but also ensures that, as it grows and evolves, the public
switched network remains a single integrated network incorporating the
traditional local and interexchange telephone networks and enabling
users to send or receive messages to or from all other users. Further,
although the Title II Order found that the revised definitions
[[Page 7866]]
adopted at that time were warranted as better reflecting current
technological developments, including the ``rapidly growing and
virtually universal use of mobile broadband service'' and the
``universal access provided . . . by and to mobile broadband,'' the
Commission expressly noted that its determination was ``a policy
judgment that section 332(d) expressly delegated to the Commission,
consistent with its broad spectrum management authority under Title
III.'' We find that this analysis places undue weight on the wide
availability of a mobile service, as being effectively available to a
substantial portion of the public is merely one of the definitional
criteria. The Commission found that the updated definitions would be
consistent with Congress's intent to create a symmetrical regulatory
framework among mobile services that were similarly ``broadly
available'' to the public. While we agree that Congress intended, in
adopting Section 332, to regulate similar mobile services
symmetrically, we do not believe that Congress intended for the
Commission to regulate mobile services symmetrically simply because
they are similarly ``broadly available.'' First, being ``effectively
available to a substantial portion of the public'' is a necessary, but
not sufficient, requirement for classification as commercial mobile
service. Second, as noted, Congress set as the touchstone for
regulatory symmetry only those mobile services that are ``functionally
equivalent.'' In light of definitional analysis discussed above, as
well as the public policy considerations that we have found to support
our decision to classify broadband internet access service as an
information service, we find under the same authority that such
developments do not persuade us to retain the modified definitions.
60. We find that mobile broadband internet access service does not
meet the regulatory definition of ``interconnected service'' that the
Commission originally adopted in 1994 and which we readopt today, and
therefore it does not meet the definition of commercial mobile service.
As the Commission found in the Wireless Broadband Internet Access
Order, ``[m]obile wireless broadband Internet access service in and of
itself does not provide the capability to communicate with all users of
the public switched network'' because it does ``not use the North
American Numbering Plan to access the Internet, which limits
subscribers' ability to communicate to or receive communications from
all users in the public switched network.'' Accordingly, it is ``not an
`interconnected service' as the Commission has defined the term in the
context of section 332.''
61. We disagree with the conclusion in the Title II Order that,
because an end user can use a separate application or service that
rides on top of the broadband internet access service for
interconnected communications, mobile broadband internet access service
meets the definition of ``interconnected service.'' We find that the
definition of ``interconnected service'' focuses on the characteristics
of the offered mobile service itself. Thus, the service in question
must itself provide interconnection to the public switched network
using the NANP to be considered an interconnected service. Our
interpretation is consistent with Commission precedent that, prior to
the Title II Order, had classified a service based on the nature of the
service itself. This interpretation is also consistent with Section
332(d)(1), which defines commercial mobile service as a service that
itself ``makes interconnected service available . . . to the public,''
and with Section 332(d)(2), which defines ``interconnected service'' as
``service that is interconnected with the public switched network.''
These statutory definitions focus on the functions of the service
itself rather than ``whether the service allows consumers to acquire
other services that bridge the gap to the telephone network.'' Thus, we
are not persuaded by arguments that ``applications such as Google Voice
reflect the fully interconnected nature of the mobile broadband and
legacy telephone networks.'' Our determination reflects that the
relevant service must itself be an ``interconnected service,'' and not
merely a capability to acquire interconnection. We further note that
viewing broadband internet access service as a distinct service from
application layer services that may be accessed by it, even if the
applications are pre-installed in the mobile device offered by the
provider, ensures that similar mobile broadband internet access
services are not regulated in a disparate fashion based on what
applications a particular provider chooses to install in their offered
devices. This is consistent with the fundamental purpose under Section
332 of regulatory symmetry between similar mobile services, and also
avoids regulatory inconsistencies that would result when mobile devices
are brought to a particular service provider by the consumer that do
not include the provider's choice of pre-installed apps. While OTI New
America argues that the need to obtain such apps to make an
interconnected call does not make mobile broadband internet access
service different from traditional telephone service, which has always
required customer premises equipment to complete an interconnected
call, we find the analogy inapt. With traditional CMRS, even where
consumers obtain their premises equipment or mobile devices separately,
the function of interconnection is provided by the purchased mobile
service itself. Because the focus is solely on the relevant service
provided, we also disagree that physical connections between networks,
in and of themselves, establish that the relevant services are
interconnected, and we further disagree that mobile broadband internet
access service should be considered an interconnected service simply
because a separate interconnected voice service may be provided using
the same packet-switched network layer.
62. Consistent with the Commission's analysis in the Wireless
Broadband Internet Access Order, the fact that ``consumers are now able
to use a variety of Internet-enabled applications that allow them to
send calls and texts to NANP end-points'' does not make mobile
broadband internet access service itself an interconnected service as
defined by our rules. The increased use and availability of mobile VoIP
applications does not change the fact that mobile broadband internet
access as a core service is distinct from the service capabilities
offered by applications (whether installed by a user or hardware
manufacturer) that may ride on top of it. When viewed as a distinct
service, it is apparent that today's mobile broadband internet access
service itself does not enable users to reach NANP telephone numbers
and therefore cannot be considered an interconnected service. We do not
here address whether IP-based services or applications such as Wi-Fi
Calling or VoLTE would meet the definition of ``interconnected
service'' under Section 332 and the Commission's rules. We disagree
with OTI New America's argument that the growing availability of Wi-Fi
Calling provided by mobile carriers that also offer mobile broadband
internet access service supports the classification of mobile broadband
internet access service as a commercial mobile service. The two are
distinct services and subject to separate classification
determinations. Similarly, even if providers are increasingly offering
voice service and mobile broadband internet access service
[[Page 7867]]
together, this does not support classifying and regulating the latter
in the same way as the former. Providers have long offered multiple
services of mixed classification, subject to the rule that they are
regulated as common carriers to the extent they offer services that are
subject to Title II regulation.
63. Moreover, in light of the determination above that mobile
broadband internet access service should be restored to its
classification as an information service, and consistent with our
findings today that reinstating this classification will serve the
public interest, we also find that it will serve the public interest
for the Commission to exercise its statutory authority to return to its
original conclusion that mobile broadband internet access is not a
commercial mobile service. We note that commenters who support the
Title II Order's revised definition of ``public switched network'' do
not dispute that Congress expressly delegated authority to the
Commission to define the key terms, i.e., ``public switched network''
and ``interconnected service.'' No one disputes that, consistent with
the Commission's previous findings, if mobile broadband internet access
service were a commercial mobile service for purposes of Section 332
and were also classified as an information service, such a regulatory
framework could lead to contradictory and absurd results. Among these
problems, as the Commission explained in 2007, is that a contrary
reading of the Act would result in an internal contradiction within the
statutory framework, because Section 332 would require that the service
provider be treated as a common carrier insofar as it provides mobile
wireless broadband internet access service, while Section 3 clearly
would prohibit the application of common carrier regulation of such a
service provider's provision of that service. Indeed, the Title II
Order, like the 2007 Wireless Broadband Internet Access Order,
recognized and sought to avoid the significant problems in construing
Section 332 in a manner that set up this ``statutory contradiction''
with the scope of Title II. Construing the CMRS definition to exclude
mobile broadband internet access service as an information service
similarly avoids this contradiction, furthers the Act's overall intent
to allow information services to develop free from common carrier
regulations, and is consistent with the public policy analysis in
connection with our determination to reclassify mobile broadband
internet access as an information service. Further, it avoids the
absurd result of singling out mobile providers of broadband internet
access service for such common carrier regulation while freeing fixed
broadband internet access services from such regulation,
notwithstanding that, as discussed elsewhere in this Order, there is
generally greater competition in the provision of mobile broadband
internet access service than in fixed broadband internet access
service. We note that wireless services similar to mobile broadband
internet access service were not available in the market place in 1993
when Congress adopted Section 332 or, in 1996, when Congress adopted
the Section 3 definition of ``telecommunication carrier.''
64. In addition to finding that mobile broadband internet access is
not a commercial mobile service, we also adopt our proposal to
reconsider the Commission's analysis regarding functional equivalence
in the Title II Order. For the same reasons discussed below with
respect to our authority to revisit the classification of broadband
internet access service, we disagree with arguments regarding limits on
the Commission's ability to revisit the Title II Order's findings
regarding functional equivalence. In addition, we note that the Title
II Order, in reaching the conclusion that mobile broadband internet
access was a commercial mobile service, relied in part on the need to
avoid a statutory contradiction with its determination that the service
was a telecommunications service. Given our decision to restore the
original classification of mobile broadband internet access service as
an information service, this change additionally warrants revisiting
our conclusions with regard to the classification of mobile broadband
internet access service under Section 332. We find that the test for
functional equivalence adopted in the Second CMRS Report and Order
reflects the best interpretation of Section 332. Under this test, a
variety of factors will be evaluated to make a determination whether
the mobile service in question is the functional equivalent of a
commercial mobile radio service, including: Consumer demand for the
service to determine whether the service is closely substitutable for a
commercial mobile radio service; whether changes in price for the
service under examination, or for the comparable commercial mobile
radio service would prompt customers to change from one service to the
other; and market research information identifying the targeted market
for the service under review. In contrast, as noted above, the Title II
Order based its finding of functional equivalence on the notion that
``like commercial mobile service, [mobile broadband Internet access] is
a widely available, for profit mobile service that offers mobile
subscribers the capability to send and receive communications on their
mobile device to and from the public.'' Commenters who support the
classification of mobile broadband internet access service as a
commercial mobile service similarly contend that mobile broadband
internet access service shares no similarities with other private
mobile services such as taxi dispatch services and that, in contrast,
``there is no networked service more open, interconnected, and
universally offered than mobile broadband Internet access service.'' We
note that the statute directs us to determine whether mobile broadband
internet access is functionally equivalent to a commercial mobile
service, not whether it is functionally dissimilar from certain systems
classified as private mobile.
65. We believe the test of functional equivalence adopted in the
Second CMRS Report and Order hews much more faithfully to the intent of
Congress than the approach applied in the Title II Order or the
analyses in the record focusing on the extent of service availability.
If Congress meant for widespread public access to a widely used service
to be the determining factor for what is ``functionally equivalent'' to
a commercial mobile service, it would not have included being
``interconnected with the public switched network'' in the statutory
definition of the service. Indeed, the relevant House Report, in
describing ``private carriers'' that under the current law were
offering service ``[f]unctionally . . . indistinguishable'' from
carriers classified as common carriers, highlighted that these private
carriers were offering services interconnected with the public switched
network. Although the Commission has discretion to determine whether
services are functionally equivalent, we find that the Title II Order's
reliance on the public's ``ubiquitous access'' to mobile broadband
internet access service alone was insufficient to establish functional
equivalency. In contrast, the test established in the Second CMRS
Report and Order provides a thorough consideration of factors that are
indicative of whether a service is closely substitutable in the eyes of
consumers for a commercial mobile service.
66. Applying the test adopted by the Commission in the Second CMRS
Report and Order, we find that mobile broadband internet access service
today is not the functional equivalent of
[[Page 7868]]
commercial mobile service as defined by the Commission. We note again
that, under this test, services not meeting the definition of
commercial mobile service are presumed to be not functionally
equivalent, a presumption particularly intuitive here in light of the
functional differences between traditional commercial mobile services
like mobile voice and today's mobile broadband services. The evidence
on demand substitutability only reinforces this presumption. First,
mobile broadband internet access service and traditional mobile voice
services have different service characteristics and intended uses.
Consumers purchase mobile broadband internet access service to access
the internet, on-line video, games, search engines, websites, and
various other applications, while they purchase mobile voice service
solely to make calls to other users using NANP numbers. Pricing and
marketing information similarly support the conclusion that today
mobile broadband internet access service and traditional mobile voice
services are not ``closely substitutable.'' Such evidence suggests, for
example, that mobile service providers target different types of
customer groups when advertising voice, as opposed to mobile broadband
internet access service. Moreover, at this time, voice-only mobile
services tend to be much less expensive than mobile broadband internet
access services, and they appear to be targeted to consumers who seek
low-cost mobile service. Currently, for example, unlimited voice and
text only plans may range from $15 to $25 per month. In contrast,
unlimited mobile broadband internet plans may range from $60 to $90 per
month for a single line. Nothing in the record suggests that changing
the price for one service by a small but significant percentage would
prompt a significant percentage of customers to move to the other
service. Accordingly, under the functional equivalence standard adopted
in the CMRS Second Report and Order, we find that mobile broadband
internet access today is not the functional equivalent of commercial
mobile service. The two services have different service characteristics
and intended uses and are not closely substitutable for each other, as
evidenced by the fact that changes in price for one service generally
will not prompt significant percentages of customers to change from one
service to the other. We make a conforming revision to the definition
of ``commercial mobile radio service'' in Section 20.3 of the
Commission's rules to reflect our determination that mobile broadband
internet access service is not the functional equivalent of commercial
mobile service.
C. Public Policy Supports Classifying Broadband Internet Access Service
as an Information Service
67. While our legal analysis concluding that broadband internet
access service is best classified as an information service under the
Act is sufficient grounds alone on which to base our classification
decision, the public policy arguments advanced in the record and
economic analysis reinforce that conclusion. We find that reinstating
the information service classification for broadband internet access
service is more likely to encourage broadband investment and
innovation, furthering our goal of making broadband available to all
Americans and benefitting the entire internet ecosystem. For almost 20
years, there was a bipartisan consensus that broadband should remain
under Title I, and ISPs cumulatively invested $1.5 trillion in
broadband networks between 1996 and 2015. Commenters who claim recent
growth in online video streaming services is evidence of the need for
Title II regulation ignore the fact that the growth of online video
streaming services was largely made possible by the network investments
made under Title I and as such demonstrates instead the success of the
longstanding light-touch framework under Title I. During that period of
intense investment, broadband deployment and adoption increased
dramatically, as the combined number of fixed and mobile internet
connections increased from 50.2 million to 355.2 million from 2005 to
2015, and even as early as 2011, a substantial majority of Americans
had access to broadband at home. As of 2016, roughly 91 percent of
homes had access to networks offering 25 Mbps, and there were 395.9
million wireless connections, twenty percent more than the U.S.
population. Mobile data speeds have also dramatically increased, with
speeds increasing 40-fold from the 3G speeds of 2007. Cable broadband
speeds increased 3,200 percent between 2005 and 2015, while prices per
Mbps fell by more than 87 percent between 1996 and 2012.
68. Based on the record in this proceeding, we conclude that
economic theory, empirical studies, and observational evidence support
reclassification of broadband internet access service as an information
service rather than the application of public-utility style regulation
on ISPs. We find the Title II classification likely has resulted, and
will result, in considerable social cost, in terms of foregone
investment and innovation. At the same time, classification of
broadband internet access service under Title II has had no discernable
incremental benefit relative to Title I classification. The regulations
promulgated under the Title II regime appear to have been a solution in
search of a problem. Close examination of the examples of harm cited by
proponents of Title II to justify heavy-handed regulation reveal that
they are sparse and often exaggerated. Moreover, economic incentives,
including competitive pressures, support internet openness. We find
that the gatekeeper theory, the bedrock of the Title II Order's overall
argument justifying its approach, is a poor fit for the broadband
internet access service market. Further, even if there may be potential
harms, we find that pre-existing legal remedies, particularly antitrust
and consumer protection laws, sufficiently address such harms so that
they are outweighed by the well-recognized disadvantages of public
utility regulation. As such, we find that public policy considerations
support our legal finding that broadband internet access service is an
information service under the Act.
1. Title II Regulation Imposes Substantial Costs on the Internet
Ecosystem
69. The Commission has long recognized that regulatory burdens and
uncertainty, such as those inherent in Title II, can deter investment
by regulated entities and, until the Title II Order, its regulatory
framework for cable, wireline, and wireless broadband internet access
services reflected that reality. Congress has similarly recognized the
burdens associated with regulation. For example, the 1996 Act states
its purpose is to ``reduce regulation,'' and directs the Commission to
regularly review regulations and repeal those it deems unnecessary or
harmful to investment, competition, and the public interest. This
concern is well-documented in the economics literature on regulatory
theory, and the record also supports the theory that the regulation
imposed by Title II will negatively impact investment. The balance of
the evidence in the record suggests that Title II classification has
reduced ISP investment in broadband networks, as well as hampered
innovation, because of regulatory uncertainty. The record also
demonstrates that small ISPs, many of which serve rural consumers, have
been particularly harmed by Title II. And there is no convincing
evidence of increased investment in the edge that
[[Page 7869]]
would compensate for the reduction in network investment.
70. Investment by ISPs. As the Commission has noted in the past,
increased broadband deployment and subscribership require investment,
and the regulatory climate affects investment. The mechanisms by which
public utility regulation can depress investment by the regulated
entity are well-known in the regulatory economics literature. The
owners of network infrastructure make long-term, irreversible
investments. In theory, public utility regulation is intended to curb
monopoly pricing just enough that the firm earns a rate of return on
its investments equivalent to what it would earn in a competitive
market. In practice, public utility regulation can depress profits
below the competitive rate of return for a variety of reasons. This
reduction in the expected return reduces the incentive to invest.
Importantly, the risk that regulation might push returns below the
competitive level also creates a disincentive for investment.
71. We first look to broadband investment in the aggregate and find
that it has decreased since the adoption of the Title II Order. ISP
capital investment increased each year from the end of the recession in
2009 until 2014, when it peaked. In 2015, capital investment by
broadband providers appears to have declined for the first time since
the end of the recession in 2009. And investment levels fell again in
2016--down more than 3 percent from 2014 levels. Although declines in
broadband capital investments have occurred in the past with changes in
the business cycle, the most recent decline is particularly curious
given that the economy has not experienced a recession in recent years
but rather has been growing. While observing trends in the data by
itself cannot establish the cause of directional movements, the stark
trend reversal that has developed in recent years suggests that changes
to the regulatory environment created by the Title II Order have
stifled investment. In addition to data trends, the record contains a
variety of other studies, using different methodologies which seek to
determine how imposition of public-utility style regulation might
affect ISPs' investments.
72. Comparisons of ISP investment before and after the Title II
Order suggest that reclassification has discouraged investment.
Performing such a comparison, economist Hal Singer concluded that ISP
investment by major ISPs fell by 5.6 percent between 2014 and 2016.
Singer attempted to account for a few significant factors unrelated to
Title II that might affect investment, by subtracting some investments
that are clearly not affected by the regulatory change (such as the
accounting treatment of Sprint's telephone handsets, AT&T's investments
in Mexico, and DirecTV investments following its acquisition by AT&T in
the middle of this period). In contrast, Free Press presents statistics
that it claims demonstrate that broadband deployment and ISP investment
``accelerated'' to ``historic levels'' after the Commission approved
the Title II Order. But Free Press fails to account for factors such as
foreign investment and the appropriate treatment of handsets as capital
expenditures, as Singer did.
73. A comparative assessment that adjusted the Free Press and
Singer numbers so that they covered the same ISPs, spanned the same
time period, and subtracted investments unaffected by the regulatory
change, found that both sets of numbers demonstrate that ISP investment
fell by about 3 percent in 2015 and by 2 percent in 2016. A Free State
Foundation calculation using broadband capital expenditure data for 16
of the largest ISPs reached a result similar to Singer's, but this
analysis simply compared actual ISP investment to a trend extrapolated
from pre-2015 data. These types of comparisons can only be regarded as
suggestive, since they fail to control for other factors that may
affect investment (such as technological change, the overall state of
the economy, and the fact that large capital investments often occur in
discrete chunks rather than being spaced evenly over time), and
companies may take several years to adjust their investment plans.
Nonetheless, these comparisons are consistent with other evidence in
the record that indicates that Title II adversely affected broadband
investment. A separate comparison of the United States' ISP investment
with ISP investment in Europe also suggests that ISP investment might
decline further if the U.S., under the Title II Order, moves toward a
regulatory system more like Europe's. A USTelecom research brief finds
that European investment per capita is about 50 percent lower than
broadband investment in the U.S. per capita. As some commenters point
out, this study compares the U.S. with the much more regulatory
European system, which includes mandatory unbundling at regulated
rates. Thus, it presents a picture of how investment could change if
the U.S. moves toward the European system under Title II, not an
assessment of the direct results of the Title II Order.
74. The record also contains analyses attempting to assess the
predicted causal effects of Title II regulation on ISP investment and/
or output. Some of these studies are ``natural experiments'' that seek
to compare outcomes occurring after policy changes to a relevant
counterfactual that shows what outcomes would have occurred in the
absence of the policy change. No single study is dispositive, but
methodologies designed to estimate impacts relative to a counterfactual
tend to provide more convincing evidence of causal impacts of Title II
classification. Having reviewed the record of these studies, the
balance of the evidence indicates that Title II discourages investment
by ISPs--a finding consistent with economic theory. The record does not
provide sufficient evidence to quantify the size of the effect of Title
II on investment. An additional type of evidence is the effect of the
Title II Order on stock prices. According to that study, in the short
term, the decision appears to have had little direct effect on stock
prices, except for a few cable ISPs. That may reflect the forward-
looking, predictive capabilities of market players.
75. Prior FCC regulatory decisions provide a natural experiment
allowing this question to be studied. Scholars employing the natural
experiment approach found that prior to 2003, subscribership to cable
modem service (not regulated under Title II) grew at a far faster rate
than subscribership to DSL internet access service (the underlying
`last mile' facilities and transmission which were regulated under
Title II). After 2003, when the Commission removed line-sharing rules
on DSL, DSL internet access service subscribership experienced a
statistically significant upward shift relative to cable modem service.
A second statistically significant upward shift in DSL internet access
service subscribership relative to cable modem service occurred after
the Commission classified DSL internet access service as an information
service in 2005. This evidence suggests that Title II discourages not
just ISP investment, but also deployment and subscribership, which
ultimately create benefits for consumers. While some commenters contend
that deployment and subscribership continued to increase after the
Title II Order, such that nothing is amiss, this casual observation
does not compare observed levels of subscribership and deployment to a
relevant counterfactual that controls for other factors.
[[Page 7870]]
76. An assessment of how ISP investment reacted to news of
impending Title II regulation suggests that the threat of Title II
regulation discouraged ISP investment. Such statistical analysis allows
one to compare the actual level of investment with a counterfactual
estimate of what investment would have been in the absence of the
change in risk. This study found that Chairman Genachowski's 2010
announcement of a framework for reclassifying broadband under Title
II--a credible increase in the risk of reclassification that surprised
financial markets--was associated with a $30 billion-$40 billion annual
decline in investment in the U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis'
``broadcasting and telecommunications'' category between 2011 and 2015.
The study attributes the decline to the threat of Title II regulation,
rather than net neutrality per se, because no similar decline occurred
when the FCC adopted the four principles to promote an open internet in
2005. Because the study's measure of investment data covers the entire
broadcasting and telecommunications industries, the change in
investment measured in this study might be larger than the change in
broadband investment associated with the threat of Title II regulation.
Accordingly, the findings may be a more reliable indicator of the
direction of the change in investment than the absolute size of the
change. At the very least, the study suggests that news of impending
Title II regulation is associated with a reduction in ISP investment
over a multi-year period.
77. Some commenters have argued that this study does not identify
the effect of Title II on ISP investment, because the ``last mile''
facilities and transmission underlying DSL internet access service
(essentially incumbent LEC broadband supply) were under Title II before
2005, during the study's pre-treatment period. However, to the extent
that a fraction of the industry was subject to Title II (and at the
time the bulk of broadband subscribers used cable modem services that
were not regulated under Title II), this would imply Ford's negative
result for investment was understated.
78. The study is also disputed by the Internet Association, which
submitted an economic study arguing that the threat and eventual
imposition of Title II status on broadband internet service providers
in 2010 and 2015 did not have a measurable impact on telecommunications
investment in the U.S. While we appreciate the alternative method and
data sources introduced by that study, several elements lead us to
discount its findings. The estimation of the impact of events in both
2010 and 2015 relies partially on forecast rather than actual data,
which likely lessens the possibility of finding an effect of Title II
on investment. In addition, when examining cable and telecommunications
infrastructure investment in the U.S., the study relies on a regression
discontinuity over time model, thereby eliminating the use of a
separate control group to identify the effect of policy changes. We
believe use of such a model in these circumstances is unlikely to yield
reliable results. The Internet Association study claims that its test
of the 2010 effect did not use forecast data. However, comparing the
reported number of observations in Tables B1 and B2 of the study
clearly indicates that the same datasets were used to estimate 2010 and
2015 effects. Furthermore, we note that the Phoenix Center attempted to
replicate the results of Table B1 and obtained strikingly different
results when excluding the forecast data. Unfortunately, the Phoenix
Center chose to only estimate Hooton's baseline model, which did not
control for obviously confounding factors such as the business cycle,
and therefore we place limited weight on the Phoenix Center's
revisions.
79. In light of the foregoing record evidence, we conclude that
reclassification of broadband internet access service from Title II to
Title I is likely to increase ISP investment and output. The studies in
the record that control the most carefully for other factors that may
affect investment (the Ford study and the Hazlett & Wright study)
support this conclusion. Ford controls for macroeconomic factors that
influence the overall economy using a two-way fixed-effects model.
Hazlett & Wright's analysis of the effects of Title II on DSL
subscribership cites regression analysis that controls for factors
influencing the overall economy by including Canadian DSL
subscribership as an explanatory variable. Consequently, we disagree
with commenters who assert that Title II has increased or had no effect
on ISP investment, given the failure of other studies to account for
complexity of corporate decision-making and the macroeconomic effects
that can play a role in investment cycles. We also disagree with
commenters who assert that it may be too soon to meaningfully assess
the economic effects that Title II has had on broadband infrastructure
investment.
80. Regulatory Uncertainty. The evidence that Title II has
depressed broadband investment is bolstered by other record evidence
showing that Title II stifled network innovation. Among the unseen
social costs of regulation are those broadband innovations and
developments that never see the light of day. ISP investment does not
simply take the form of greater deployment, but can also be directed
toward new and more advanced services for consumers. Research and
development is an inherently risky part of any business, and the
Commission's actions should not introduce greater uncertainty and risk
into the process without a clear need to do so. Numerous commenters
have stated that the uncertainty regarding what is allowed and what is
not allowed under the new Title II broadband regime has caused them to
shelve projects that were in development, pursue fewer innovative
business models and arrangements, or delay rolling out new features or
services. Even large ISPs with significant resources have not been
immune to the dampening effect that uncertainty can have on a firm's
incentive to innovate. Charter, for instance, has asserted that it has
``put on hold a project to build out its out-of-home Wi-Fi network, due
in part to concerns about whether future interpretations of Title II
would allow Charter to continue to offer its Wi-Fi network as a benefit
to its existing subscribers.'' Cox has also stated that it has
approached the ``development and launch of new products and service
features with greater caution'' due to the uncertainty created by the
Title II classification. And while new service offerings can take a
while to develop and launch, Comcast cites ``Title II overhang'' as a
burden that delayed the launch of its IP-based transmission of its
cable service, due to a year-long investigation.
81. Utility-style regulation is particularly inapt for a dynamic
industry built on technological development and disruption. It is well
known that extensive regulation distorts production as well as
consumption choices. Regulated entities are inherently restricted in
the activities in which they may engage, and the products that they may
offer. Asking permission to engage in new activities or offer new
products or services quickly becomes a major preoccupation of the
utility. This is apparent upon a casual observation of heavily-
regulated utilities, such as the U.S. power, water, and mass transit
systems. These are industries where competition has been effectively
deemed impossible, run by quasi-public monopolies that lack incentives
to invest, innovate, or even properly maintain their facilities.
[[Page 7871]]
Within the communications industry, it is apparent that the most
regulated sectors, such as basic telephone service, have experienced
the least innovation, whereas those sectors that have been
traditionally free to innovate, such as internet service, have greatly
evolved. In the communications industry, incumbents have often used
Commission regulation under the direction of the ``public interest'' to
thwart innovation and competitive entry into the sector and protect
existing market structures. Given the unknown needs of the networks of
the future, it is our determination that the utility-style regulations
potentially imposed by Title II run contrary to the public interest.
82. The record confirms that concern about ``regulatory creep''--
whereby a regulator slowly increases its reach and the scope of its
regulations--has exacerbated the regulatory uncertainty created by the
Title II Order. Even at the time of adoption, the Commission itself did
not seem to know how the Title II Order would be interpreted. As then-
Chairman Wheeler stated in February 2015, ``we don't really know. No
blocking, no throttling, no fast lanes. Those can be bright-line rules
because we know about those issues. But we don't know where things go
next.'' With future regulations open to such uncertainties, Title II
regulation adds a risk premium on each investment decision, which
reduces the expected profitability of potential investments and deters
investment. For example, the Title II Order did not forbear from ex
post enforcement actions related to subscriber charges, raising
concerns that ex post price regulation was very much a possibility.
Further, providers have asserted that although the Commission forbore
from the full weight of Title II in the Title II Order, they were less
willing to invest due to concerns that the Commission could reverse
course in the future and impose a variety of costly regulations on the
broadband industry--such as rate regulation and unbundling/open access
requirements--placing any present investments in broadband
infrastructure at risk. These concerns were compounded by the fact that
while the Title II Order itself announced forbearance from ex ante
price regulation, at the same time it imposed price regulation with its
ban on paid prioritization arrangements, which mandated that ISPs
charge edge providers a zero price. These threats to the ISP business
model have been felt throughout financial markets. As Craig Moffett of
MoffettNathanson explained, ``[i]t would be na[iuml]ve to suggest that
the implication of Title II, particularly when viewed in the context of
the FCC's repeated findings that the broadband market is non-
competitive, doesn't introduce a real risk of price regulation.'' These
risks are not merely theoretical: As CenturyLink contends, financial
analysts lowered industry stock ratings due in part to the major risks
Title II posed to the industry, which resulted in lower stock prices
and lost market capitalization.
83. For these reasons, ``any rational ISP will think twice before
investing in innovative business plans that might someday be found to
violate the Commission's undisclosed policy preferences and thus give
rise to a cease-and-desist order and perhaps massive forfeiture
penalties.'' We conclude that this ever-present threat of regulatory
creep is substantially likely to affect the risk calculus taken by ISPs
when deciding how to invest their shareholders' capital, potentially
deterring them from investing in broadband, and to encourage them to
direct capital toward less inherently-risky business operations. Many
ISPs are part of integrated multi-sector holding companies, which
allows them to more easily shift capital away from sectors where their
investments would face greater regulatory risk, and toward more
investment-friendly sectors. We find unpersuasive the alleged
inconsistencies between ISPs claiming that the Title II Order decreased
their willingness or ability to invest in broadband infrastructure, and
their statements to investors that the Title II Order has not had a
negative impact on their broadband deployments. First, some of the
comments claiming that corporate officers' statements to investors
prove that Title II has increased investment use highly selective
quotations that ignore other statements to investors that imply the
opposite. Second, as other commenters point out, the latter often
constitute statements susceptible to multiple interpretations, such as
AT&T CEO Randall Stephenson stating that his company planned to
``deploy more fiber next year than [it] did this year.'' Third, these
ambiguous statements do not take into account the relevant
counterfactual scenario in which Title II regulation had not been
adopted. Fourth, we observe that some of the comments attempting to
highlight a discrepancy between statements to investors and statements
in this proceeding simply show executives stating that their business
practices will not change because they were not engaged in the conduct
prohibited by the Title II Order, not that the firms' investment
priorities remained the same after the Title II Order. As such, we
disagree with commenters who assert that maintaining the Title II Order
regime is the best means of addressing regulatory uncertainty.
84. Small ISPs and Rural Communities. The Commission's decision in
2015 to reclassify broadband internet access service as a
telecommunications service has had particularly deleterious effects on
small ISPs and the communities they serve, which are often rural and/or
lower-income. The record reflects that small ISPs and new entrants into
the market face disproportionate costs and burdens as a result of
regulation. Many small ISPs lack the extensive resources necessary to
comply with burdensome regulation, and the record evinces a widespread
consensus that reclassification of broadband internet access service as
a telecommunications service has harmed small ISPs by forcing them to
divert significant resources to legal compliance and deterring them
from taking financial risks.
85. Small ISPs state that these increased compliance costs and
regulatory burdens have forced them to divert money and attention away
from planned broadband service and network upgrades and expansions,
thus delaying, deferring, or forgoing the benefits they would have
brought ``to their bottom lines, their customers, and their
communities.'' A coalition of National Multicultural Organizations
highlights that the uncertainty inherent under Title II ``already has
produced results that slow needed innovation and broadband adoption,
effects that are most acutely felt in rural and socioeconomically-
challenged urban communities.'' The record is replete with instances in
which small ISPs reduced planned, or limited new, investment in
broadband infrastructure as a result of the regulatory uncertainty
stemming from the adoption of the Title II Order. Because the logical
expectation that Title II regulation would have particularly harmful
effects on small ISPs and the communities they serve in is borne out by
strong record evidence from a wide range of small ISPs, we are
unpersuaded by speculative suggestions that small ISPs' investment
decisions can be fully or primarily explained based on other
considerations such that the effect of Title II regulation can be
neglected. The Wireless Internet Service Providers Association (WISPA)
surveyed its members and found that over 80 percent had ``incurred
additional expense in complying with
[[Page 7872]]
the Title II rules, had delayed or reduced network expansion, had
delayed or reduced services and had allocated budget to comply with the
rules.'' The threat of ex post rate regulation has hung particularly
heavily on the heads of small ISPs, ``who are especially risk-averse,
causing them to run all current and planned offerings against the
`just' and `reasonable' and unreasonably discriminatory standards of
sections 201 and 202 of the Act.'' The effects have been strongly felt
by small ISPs, given their more limited resources, leading to depressed
hiring in rural areas most in need of additional resources.
86. Compounding the difficulties faced by small ISPs, the record
also reflects that the `` `black cloud' of common carriage
regulations'' resulted in increased difficulties for small ISPs in
obtaining financing. A coalition of 70 small wireless ISPs cited the
uncertainty created by the Title II Order as a major reason that their
costs of capital have risen, preventing them from further expanding and
improving their networks. The new regulatory burdens, risks, and
uncertainties combined with ``diminished access to capital create a
vicious cycle--the regulatory burdens make it more difficult to attract
capital, and less capital makes it more difficult to comply with
regulatory burdens.'' A coalition of 19 municipal ISPs cited high legal
and consulting fees necessary to navigate the Title II Order, as well
as regulatory compliance risk as a reason for delaying or abandoning
new features and services. While, of course, not all small ISPs have
faced these challenges, there is substantial record evidence that
regulatory uncertainty resulting from the Commission's reclassification
of broadband internet access service in 2015 risks stifling innovation,
and that it has already done so with respect to small ISPs, which
ultimately harms consumers.
87. We anticipate that the beneficial effects of our decision today
to restore the classification of broadband internet access service to
an information service will be particularly felt in rural and/or lower-
income communities, giving smaller ISPs a stronger business case to
expand into currently unserved areas. Enabling ISPs to freely
experiment with services and business arrangements that can best serve
their customers, without excessive regulatory and compliance burdens,
is an important factor in connecting underserved and hard-to-reach
populations. We are committed to bridging the digital divide, and
recognize that small ISPs ``disproportionately provide service in rural
and underserved areas where they are either the only available
broadband service option or provide the only viable alternative to an
incumbent broadband provider.'' We anticipate that returning broadband
internet access service to a light-touch regulatory framework will help
further the Commission's statutory imperative to ``encourage the
deployment on a reasonable and timely basis of advanced
telecommunications capability to all Americans'' by helping to
incentivize ISPs to expand coverage to underserved areas. We therefore
reject arguments that our classification decision harms low-income
communities.
88. Investment at the Edge. Finally, to more fully discern the
impact of Title II, we must look at investment throughout the broadband
ecosystem, including investment and innovation at the edge, as well as
with other ecosystem participants (manufacturers, etc.). We agree with
commenters who assert that looking only at ISP investment ignores
investment that is occurring at the edge. While there is tremendous
investment occurring at the edge, the record does not suggest a
correlation between edge provider investment and Title II regulation,
nor does it suggest a causal relationship that edge providers have
increased their investments as a result of the Title II Order. Free
Press argues that since adoption of the Title II Order, innovation and
investment at the edge has increased. While high growth rates are
associated with the internet industry, the evidence presented does not
show the imposition of Title II regulation on internet access service
providers caused recent edge provider investment. That requires an
estimate as to what would have happened in the absence of Title II
regulation (e.g., analysis following the methods employed in the
studies of Ford, and of Hazlett & Wright).
89. In fact, one could argue that in the absence of Title II
regulation, edge providers would have made even higher levels of
investment than they undertook. In many cases, the strongest growth for
a firm or industry predates the Title II Order. For example, Free Press
highlights that the data processing, hosting, and related services
industry increased capital expenditures by 26 percent in 2015, a
significant increase in investment. However, in 2013, well before the
2014 Open Internet NPRM that led to the Title II Order, that industry
increased investment by over 100 percent. Similarly, Netflix's greatest
relative increase in capital expenditures occurred in 2013. Amazon
increased its spending on technology and content, which consists
primarily of research and development expenses, by 28 percent in 2016,
while in 2013 the increase was 41 percent. We do not claim that these
data points prove that edge provider investment would have been greater
in the absence of the Title II Order, but we find that Free Press does
not demonstrate that there is a significant difference in the
investment behavior of edge providers due to the Title II Order.
2. Utility-Style Regulation of Broadband Is a Solution in Search of a
Problem
90. The internet was open before Title II, and many economic
factors support openness. The internet thrived for decades under the
light-touch regulatory regime in place before the Title II Order, as
ISPs built networks and edge services were born. We find that the
sparse evidence of harms discussed in the Title II Order--evidence
repeated by commenters in this proceeding as the basis for adopting a
Title II classification--demonstrates that the incremental benefits of
Title II over light-touch regulation are inconsequential, and pale in
comparison to the significant costs of public-utility regulation. We
therefore reject the argument that sparse evidence of harms is
sufficient to justify the imposition of Title II.
91. The internet as we know it developed and flourished under
light-touch regulation. It is self-evident that the hypothetical harms
against which the Title II Order purported to protect did not thwart
the development of the internet ecosystem. Edge providers have been
able to disrupt a multitude of markets--finance, transportation,
education, music, video distribution, social media, health and fitness,
and many more--through innovation, all without subjecting the networks
that carried them to onerous utility regulation. It is telling that the
Title II Order and its proponents in this proceeding can point only to
a handful of incidents that purportedly affected internet openness,
while ignoring the two decades of flourishing innovation that preceded
the Title II Order.
92. The first instance of actual harm cited by the Title II Order
involved Madison River Communications, a small DSL provider accused in
2005 of blocking ports used for VoIP applications, thereby foreclosing
competition to its telephony business. Madison River entered into a
consent decree with the Enforcement Bureau, paying $15,000 to the U.S.
Treasury and agreeing that it ``shall not block ports used for VoIP
applications or otherwise prevent customers from using VoIP
applications.'' Vonage, an over-the-top
[[Page 7873]]
VoIP provider, later confirmed in press reports that it had initiated a
complaint against Madison River at the Commission and that other small
ISPs had blocked its VoIP services.
93. Next, the Title II Order referenced Comcast's throttling of
BitTorrent, a peer-to-peer networking protocol. Comcast, which was at
the time the nation's second-largest ISP, admitted that it interfered
with about a tenth of BitTorrent TCP connections, and independent
investigations suggested that Comcast interfered with over half of
BitTorrent streams. After receiving a formal complaint about the
practice, the Commission found ``that Comcast's conduct poses a
substantial threat to both the open character and efficient operation
of the internet, and is not reasonable,'' and ordered Comcast to cease
the interference. However, the D.C. Circuit vacated the Commission's
order in Comcast.
94. Madison River and Comcast-BitTorrent--the anecdotes most
frequently cited in favor of Title II regulation--demonstrate that any
problematic conduct was quite rare. The more recent incidents discussed
in the Title II Order also show that since 2008, few tangible threats
to the openness of the internet have arisen. First, in 2012, AT&T
restricted customers on certain data plans from accessing FaceTime on
its cellular network for three months. AT&T contended it did so due to
network management concerns, while application developers argued the
restriction limited consumer choice. Regardless of the merits, AT&T
ultimately reversed its decision within three months and the decision
did not affect consumers who had data caps.
95. The final example--though not an example of harm to consumers--
discussed in the Title II Order was Comcast's Xfinity TV application
for the Xbox, which was criticized for exempting subscribers from their
Comcast data caps. However, the service was provided as a specialized
service, similar to certain VoIP and video offerings that use IP but
are not delivered via the public internet. Accordingly, the Xfinity
Xbox application was not subject to the 2010 or 2015 rules, as it was a
so-called ``non-BIAS data service.'' However, the Title II Order
further clouded this carve-out for innovative services by threatening
to enforce the rules adopted under the Order against ISPs if it deemed
after the fact, that those services were ``functional equivalents'' of
broadband internet access services, as the Open Internet Order had done
in 2010.
96. Certain commenters have claimed that there have been other
harms to internet openness, but most of their anecdotes do not entail
harms that the Title II Order purported to combat. Electronic Frontier
Foundation and the Internet Engineers point to a number of alleged
practices by ISPs, including stripping encryption from certain
communications, inserting JavaScript code into third-party web pages,
sending search data to third parties, and adding cookies. However, none
of the bright-line rules promulgated in the Title II Order would have
halted these practices, and whether they are covered by the ``general
conduct rule'' is at best unclear. Similarly, the claim among several
commenters that certain mobile providers blocked Google Wallet is
misleading. Mobile providers refused to support Google Wallet because
it required integration with the secure element of the handset's SIM
card, which mobile providers believed introduced security
vulnerabilities. OTI's argument about AT&T blocking Slingbox--which
``redirected a TV signal'' to the iPhone app--from its 3G network in
2009 fails to provide support for Title II regulation for a similar
reason, because as AT&T explained at the time, ``we don't restrict
users from going to a website that lets them view videos. But what our
terms and conditions prohibit is the transferring, or slinging, of a TV
signal to their personal computer or smartphone.'' In an attempt to
manage its 3G network, AT&T restricted slinging to Wi-Fi, while
reiterating that consumers could still access video streaming websites.
We also recognize the existence of consumer complaints, but for the
reasons discussed in Part IV.B below, we do not find them indicative of
actual harm that the Commission's net neutrality rules are intended to
protect against.
97. Because of the paucity of concrete evidence of harms to the
openness of the internet, the Title II Order and its proponents have
heavily relied on purely speculative threats. We do not believe
hypothetical harms, unsupported by empirical data, economic theory, or
even recent anecdotes, provide a basis for public-utility regulation of
ISPs. Indeed, economic theory demonstrates that many of the practices
prohibited by the Title II Order can sometimes harm consumers and
sometimes benefit consumers; therefore, it is not accurate to presume
that all hypothetical effects are harmful. Intrusive, investment-
inhibiting Title II regulation requires a showing of actual harms, and
after roughly fifteen years of searching, proponents of Title II have
found ``astonishing[ly]'' few. Further, the transparency rule we adopt
today will require ISPs to clearly disclose such practices and this,
coupled with existing consumer protection and antitrust laws, will
significantly reduce the likelihood that ISPs will engage in actions
that would harm consumers or competition. To the extent that our
approach relying on transparency requirements, consumer protection
laws, and antitrust laws does not address all concerns, we find that
any remaining unaddressed harms are small relative to the costs of
implementing more heavy-handed regulation.
98. Incentives. We find, based on the record before us, that ISPs
have strong incentives to preserve internet openness, and these
interests typically outweigh any countervailing incentives an ISP might
have. Consequently, Title II regulation is an unduly heavy-handed
approach to what, at worst, are relatively minor problems. Although the
Title II Order argued that ISPs were incentivized to harm edge
innovation, it also conceded that ISPs benefit from the openness of the
internet. The Title II Order found that ``when a broadband provider
acts as a gatekeeper, it actually chokes consumer demand for the very
broadband product it can supply.'' We agree. The content and
applications produced by edge providers often complement the broadband
internet access service sold by ISPs, and ISPs themselves recognize
that their businesses depend on their customers' demand for edge
content. It is therefore no surprise that many ISPs have committed to
refrain from blocking or throttling lawful internet conduct
notwithstanding any Title II regulation. Finally, to the extent these
economic forces fail in any particular situation, existing consumer
protection and antitrust laws additionally protect consumers. We
therefore find that Title II, and the attendant utility-style
regulation of ISPs, are an unnecessarily heavy-handed approach to
protecting internet openness.
99. The Open Internet and Title II Orders claimed to base their
actions on a theory that broadband adoption is driven by a ``virtuous
cycle,'' whereby edge provider development ``increase[s] end-user
demand for [Internet access services], which [drive] network
improvements, which in turn lead to further innovative network uses.''
While the primary reason for this seems to be concern about the
exercise of market power, footnote 68 suggests a secondary reason: ISPs
``will typically not take into account the effect that reduced edge
provider investment and innovation has on the attractiveness of the
internet to
[[Page 7874]]
end users that rely on other broadband providers--and will therefore
ignore a significant fraction of the cost of foregone innovation.''
However, neither the Open Internet Order nor our record provide a
mechanism to explain how this would occur, and why the impact on the
ISP would not be proportional to its own business, and so be fully
accounted for in its decisions, and provides no evidence that even if
possible, there was a measurable impact from such an effect. The Title
II Order concluded that Commission action was necessary to protect this
virtuous cycle because ``gatekeeper'' power on the part of ISPs might
otherwise thwart it, as ISPs ``are unlikely to fully account for the
detrimental impact on edge providers' ability and incentive to innovate
and invest.'' However, the economic analysis in the Open Internet Order
and Title II Order was at best only loosely based on the existing
economics literature, in some cases contradicted peer-reviewed
economics literature, and included virtually no empirical evidence.
100. We find it essential to take a holistic view of the market(s)
supplied by ISPs. ISPs, as well as edge providers, are important
drivers of the virtuous cycle, and regulation must be evaluated
accounting for its impact on ISPs' capacity to drive that cycle, as
well as that of edge providers. The underlying economic model of the
virtuous cycle is that of a two-sided market. Notably, the two-sided
market we discuss here is the economic concept; we are not attempting
to define a market for antitrust purposes. In a two-sided market,
intermediaries--ISPs in our case--act as platforms facilitating
interactions between two different customer groups, or sides of the
market--edge providers and end users. The Open Internet Order takes the
position that edge provider innovation drives consumer adoption of
internet access and platform upgrades. The key characteristic of a two-
sided market, however, is that participants on each side of the market
value a platform service more as the number and/or quality of
participants on the platform's other side increases. (The benefits
subscribers on one side of the market bring to the subscribers on the
other, and vice versa, are called positive externalities.) Thus, rather
than a single side driving the market, both sides generate network
externalities, and the platform provider profits by inducing both sides
of the market to use its platform. In maximizing profit, a platform
provider sets prices and invests in network extension and innovation,
subject to costs and competitive conditions, to maximize the gain both
sides of the market obtain from interacting across the platform. The
more competitive the market, the larger the net gains to subscribers
and edge providers. Any analysis of such a market must account for each
side of the market and the platform provider.
101. Innovation by ISPs may take the form of reduced costs, network
extension, increased reliability, responsiveness, throughput, ease of
installation, and portability. These types of innovations are as likely
to drive additional broadband adoption as are services of edge
providers. In 2016, nearly 80 percent of Americans used fixed internet
access at home. There is no evidence that the remaining nearly one-
fifth of the population are all waiting for the development of
applications that would make internet access useful to them. Rather,
the cost of broadband internet access service is a central reason for
non-adoption. ISP innovation that lowers the relative cost of internet
access service is as likely as edge innovation, if not more so, to
positively impact consumer adoption rates. Indeed, ISPs likely play a
crucial role by offering, for example, low-margin or loss-leading
offers designed to induce skeptical internet users to discover the
benefits of access. In response to a larger base of potential
customers, the returns to innovation by edge providers would be
expected to rise, thereby spurring additional innovative activity in
that segment of the market.
102. Accordingly, arguments that ISPs have other incentives to take
actions that might harm the virtuous cycle, and hence might require
costly Title II regulation, need to be explained and evaluated
empirically. In a two-sided market, three potential reasons for Title
II regulation arise: The extent to which ISPs have market power in
selling internet access to end users; the extent to which ISPs have
market power in selling to edge providers access to the ISP's
subscribers (end users), which seems to primarily be to what the
Commission and others appear to be referring when using the term
``gatekeeper''; and the extent to which the positive externalities
present in a two-sided market might lead to market failure even in the
absence (or because of that absence) of ISP market power. In
considering each of these, we find that, where there are problems, they
have been overestimated, and can be substantially eliminated or reduced
by the more light-handed approach this order implements.
103. Our approach recognizes our limits as regulators, and is
appropriately focused on the long-lasting effects of regulatory
decisions. Thus, we seek to balance the harms that arise in the absence
of regulation against the harms of regulation, accounting for, in
particular, the effects of our actions on investment decisions that
could increase competition three to five or more years from now. This
is different from forbidding certain behavior or a merger on antitrust
grounds due to the likelihood of imminent, non-transitory price
increases. As a result, our discussion of competition need not have any
implications for conventional antitrust analysis. We note that our
reclassification of broadband internet access service as an information
service leaves the usual recourse of antitrust and consumer protection
action available to all parties. That is, heavy-handed Title II
regulation is unnecessary to enforce antitrust and consumer protection
laws.
104. Fixed ISPs Often Face Material Competitive Constraints. The
premise of Title II and other public utility regulation is that ISPs
can exercise market power sufficient to substantially distort economic
efficiency and harm end users. However, analysis of broadband
deployment data, coupled with an understanding of ISPs' underlying cost
structure, indicates fixed broadband internet access providers
frequently face competitive pressures that mitigate their ability to
exert market power. Therefore, the primary market failure rationale for
classifying broadband internet access service under Title II is absent.
Furthermore, the presence of competitive pressures in itself protects
the openness of the internet. The theory that competition is the best
way to protect consumers is the ``heart of our national economic
policy'' and the premise of the 1996 Act. We therefore find that the
competition that exists in the broadband market, combined with the
protections of our consumer protection and antitrust laws against
anticompetitive behaviors, will constrain the actions of an ISP that
attempts to undermine the openness of the internet in ways that harm
consumers, and to the extent they do not, any resulting harms are
outweighed by the harms of Title II regulation. Our discussion of
competitive effects, unless otherwise specified, does not rely on or
define any antitrust market.
105. ISP Competition in Supplying Internet Access to Households.
Starting with fixed internet access, including fixed satellite and
terrestrial fixed wireless service, competition, with
[[Page 7875]]
whatever limitations may be inherent in these different technologies,
appears to be widespread, at lower speeds for most households (we make
no finding as to whether lower speed fixed internet access services are
in the same market as higher speed fixed internet access services):
Percent of U.S. Population in Developed Census Blocks in Which Residential Fixed Broadband ISPS Reported
Deployment
[as of December 31, 2016]
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Number of providers
Speed of at least: ---------------------------------------------------------------
3+ (%) 2 (%) 1 (%) 0 (%)
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
3 Mbps down and 0.768 Mbps up................... 97.0 2.8 0.1 0.1
10 Mbps down and 1 Mbps up...................... 93.6 5.7 0.6 0.1
25 Mbps down and 3 Mbps up...................... 43.9 32.6 19.1 4.4
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
106. However, because there are questions as to the extent fixed
satellite and fixed terrestrial wireless internet access service are
broadly effective competitors for wireline internet access service, we
do not rely on this data, except to note that these services, where
available, place some competitive constraints on wireline providers.
Fixed wireless and satellite subscriptions decisions suggest that
consumers generally prefer fixed wireline services to these, even at
lower speeds. For example, at bandwidths of 3 Mbps downstream and 0.768
Mbps upstream, satellite providers report deployment in 99.1 percent of
developed census blocks, but only account for 1.7 percent of
subscriptions, while terrestrial fixed wireless providers report
deployment in 38.5 percent of developed census blocks, but only account
for 0.9 percent of all subscriptions. Focusing on competition among
wireline service providers, and excluding DSL with speeds less than 3
Mbps down and 0.768 Mbps up, shows less, but still widespread,
competition:
Percent of U.S. Population in Developed Census Blocks in Which Residential Broadband Wireline ISPS Reported
Deployment
[as of December 31, 2016]
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Number of providers
Speed of at least: ---------------------------------------------------------------
3+ (%) 2 (%) 1 (%) 0 (%)
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
3 Mbps down and 0.768 Mbps up................... 12.1 67.2 16.2 4.4
10 Mbps down and 1 Mbps up...................... 9.0 58.5 26.3 6.2
25 Mbps down and 3 Mbps up...................... 5.9 45.2 39.6 9.2
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
107. While not reported, the percent of households in developed
census blocks closely tracks the entries for the percent of population
in developed census tracts. For example, approximately 79.7 percent of
U.S. households are in a census block where at least two wireline
suppliers offer speeds of at least 3 Mbps down and 0.768 Mbps up. This
table understates competition in several respects. First, even two
competing wireline ISPs place competitive constraints on each other.
ISPs' substantial sunk costs imply that competition between even two
ISPs is likely to be relatively strong. Thus, to the extent market
power exists, it is unlikely to significantly distort what would
otherwise be efficient choices. A wireline ISP, anywhere it is active,
necessarily has made substantial sunk investments. Yet, the cost of
adding another customer, or of carrying more traffic from the same
customers, is relatively low. Accordingly, a wireline ISP has strong
incentives, even when facing a single competitor, to capture customers
or induce greater use of its network, so long as its current prices
materially exceed the marginal cost of such changes. In addition,
empirical research finds that the largest benefit from competition
generally comes from the presence of a second provider, with added
benefits of additional providers falling thereafter, especially in the
presence of large sunk costs. Indeed, a wireline provider may be
willing to cut prices to as low as the incremental cost of supplying a
new customer. Thus, in this industry, even two active suppliers in a
location can be consistent with a noticeable degree of competition, and
in any case, can be expected to produce more efficient outcomes than
any regulated alternative. We do not claim that a second wireline
provider results in textbook perfect competition, but rather, given ISP
recovery of sunk investments becomes more difficult as competition
increases, and the critical nature of allowing such recovery, market
outcomes may well ensure approximately competitive rates of return.
Other industries with large sunk costs have shown that ``price declines
with the addition of the first competitor, but drops by very little
thereafter.'' Nothing in this order should be construed as finding that
these statements appropriately characterize the addition of the first
fixed wireline competitor in a particular context, only that in general
such an addition likely will have a material impact on moving prices
toward competitive levels.
108. Second, competitive pressures often have spillover effects
across a given corporation, meaning an ISP facing competition broadly,
if not universally, will tend to treat customers that do not have a
competitive choice as if they do. This is because acting badly in
uncompetitive areas may be operationally expensive (i.e., requiring
different equipment, different policies, different worker training, and
different call centers to address differing circumstances) and
reputationally expensive (e.g., even if behavior is confined to an
uncompetitive market,
[[Page 7876]]
customers in competitive markets may churn after learning about such
behavior). Accordingly (and unsurprisingly), most ISPs actively try to
minimize the discrepancies in their terms of service, network
management practices, billing systems, and other policies--even if they
offer different service tiers or pricing in different areas.
Approximately 79 percent of U.S. households are found in census blocks
that at least two wireline ISPs report serving, and approximately
another 8 percent of households are in census blocks where the unique
wireline ISP providing service in the census block faces competition
from a rival in 90 percent of the blocks it serves. Such ISPs included
the top ten ISPs when ranked by covered census blocks, and also when
ranked by households in covered census blocks, except the ninth,
Windstream. Our conclusions do not hinge on finding effective
competition everywhere. We find that competition exists in various
forms nearly everywhere and to the extent that effective competition is
not universal, the costs of Title II regulation outweigh the benefits
of our more light-touch approach.
109. The Commission's prior findings on churn in the broadband
marketplace do not dissuade us from concluding that wireline broadband
ISPs often face competitive pressures. Although the Commission has
previously found voluntary churn rates for broadband service to be
quite low, a view which some commenters echo, substantial, quantified
evidence in the record dissuades us from repeating that finding here.
Regardless, even if high churn rates make market power unlikely, low
churn rates do not per se indicate market power. For example, they may
reflect competitive actions taken by ISPs to attract customers to sign
up for contracts, and to retain existing customers, such as discount
and bonus offers. Moreover, actions such as these, and others, are
indicative of competition. For example, ISPs engage in a significant
degree of advertising, aiming to draw new subscribers and convince
subscribers to other fixed ISPs to switch providers. Similarly, ISPs
employ ``save desks'' often taking aggressive actions to convince
subscribers seeking service cancellation to continue to subscribe,
often at a discounted price. Thus, the record indicates material
competition for customers regardless of churn levels.
110. There is even greater competition in mobile wireless. Mobile
wireless ISPs face competition in most markets, with widespread and
ever extending head-to-head competition between four major carriers. As
of January 2017, at least four wireless broadband service providers
covered approximately 92 percent of the U.S. population with 3G
technology or better. Even in rural areas at least four service
providers covered approximately 69 percent of the population. These
coverage estimates represent deployment of mobile networks and do not
indicate the extent to which providers offer service to residents in
the covered areas.
111. Both the Title II Order and its supporters in the current
proceeding fail to properly account for the pressure mobile internet
access exerts on fixed, including fixed wireline, internet access
supply. While we recognize that fixed and mobile internet access have
different characteristics and capabilities, for example, typically
trading off speed and data caps limits against mobility, increasing
numbers of internet access subscribers are relying on mobile services
only. In 2015, one in five households used only mobile internet access
service to go online at home (up from one in ten in 2013), and close to
15 percent of households with incomes in excess of $100,000 (up from
six percent in 2013), exclusively used mobile internet access service
at home. New America/OTI notes that this study states that low-income
Americans are far more likely to become mobile dependent than consumers
who have higher levels of income. However, as noted above, this same
study by the U.S. Census Bureau, which includes data collected from
nearly 53,000 households, also found a significant increase in mobile-
only use by higher-income households, and that the growth in the
proportion of high-income households that exclusively use mobile
internet service at home is accelerating. Several commenters discussed
their own views on the extent to which mobile wireless might exert
competitive pressure in some instances. Competition constrains a firm's
prices if the firm is prevented from raising price to levels that
absent switching to competitors, would increase the firm's profits. The
extent of the switching need not be large. For example, with constant
unit costs, a 5% price increase would be prevented if that would lead
to slightly less than 5% of the firm's customers to either stop
consuming altogether or to switch to a rival. Suppliers of internet
access service are likely to be more sensitive to customer loss than
the case with constant marginal cost, since in general the marginal
costs of internet access service fall as subscriber numbers increase,
meaning, in addition to the revenues lost due to leaving customers,
profits are also eroded due to a rise in the average cost of supplying
those who remain. With the advent of 5G technologies promising sharply
increased mobile speeds in the near future, the pressure mobile exerts
in the broadband market place will become even more significant.
112. ISP Competition in Supplying Edge Providers Access to End
Users. On the other side of the market, to the extent ISPs have market
power in supplying edge providers, ISP prices to edge providers could
distort economic efficiency (a potential harm that is distinct from
anticompetitive behavior or because of a failure to internalize a
relevant externality). Loosely speaking, such power over an edge
provider can arise under one of two conditions: The ISP has
conventional market power over the edge provider because it controls a
substantial share of (perhaps a specific subset of) end-user
subscribers that are of interest to the edge provider, or that edge
provider's customers only subscribe to one ISP (a practice known as
single homing).
113. Narrowly focusing on fixed ISPs, Comcast, the largest wireline
ISP, has approximately one quarter of all residential subscribers in
the US, while at speeds of at least 25 Mbps down and 3 Mbps up, the
Herfindahl-Hirschman Index measure of concentration for the supply of
access to residential fixed broadband internet access service
subscribers meets the Department of Justice (DOJ) designation of
``moderately concentrated'' (DOJ considers a market with an HHI value
of between 1,500 and 2,500 to be moderately concentrated):
HHI of Served Residential Fixed Broadband Internet Access Service
Subscribers
[as of December 31, 2016]
------------------------------------------------------------------------
Speed HHI
------------------------------------------------------------------------
3 Mbps down and 0.768 Mbps up........................... 1,473
10 Mbps down and 1 Mbps up.............................. 1,743
25 Mbps down and 3 Mbps up.............................. 2,208
------------------------------------------------------------------------
114. Large shares of end-user subscribers, and/or market
concentration, however, do not seem a likely source or indicator of
conventional market power capable of significantly distorting efficient
choices, with the possible exception of edge providers whose services
require characteristics currently only available on high-speed fixed
networks (such as video, which requires both high speeds and
substantial monthly data
[[Page 7877]]
allowances, and gaming and certain other applications, which require
high speeds and low latency). Given Comcast's market share, even a
fledgling edge provider that can only be viable in the long term if it
offers service to three quarters of broadband subscribers, may not
depend on gaining access to any single provider. And calculating market
shares for wireline ISPs based on their end users may be too simplistic
if edge providers can reach end users at locations other than their
homes, such as at work, or through a mobile ISP. We reject claims that
we should entirely neglect this possibility based on assertions that
users might be limited in their ability or willingness to switch
between different options for broadband internet access in unspecified
circumstances and for unspecified reasons. In addition, ISPs have good
incentives to encourage new entrants that bring value to end users,
both because such new entrants directly increase the value of the
platform's service, and because they place competitive pressure on
other edge providers, forcing lower prices, again increasing the value
of the platform's service. Moreover, those smaller edge providers may
benefit from tiered pricing, such as paid prioritization, as a means of
gaining entry. If the entrant offers a more valuable service than an
incumbent, then this would be a profitable strategy, and while it is
common to claim new entrants would not have the deep pockets necessary
to implement such an entry strategy, new economy startups have
demonstrated that capital markets are willing to provide funds for
potentially profitable ideas, despite high failure rates, presumably
because of the large potential gains when an entrant is successful.
Examples of successful new entrants that started behind dominant
incumbents, include Google (against established search engines such as
Yahoo, and the map provider, MapQuest), Amazon (against traditional
bricks and mortar storefronts), and Facebook (against MySpace). In
fact, some edge providers might consider reaching end users on mobile
devices to be roughly as valuable as, or more valuable than, reaching
end users on wireline networks.
115. In addition, larger edge providers, such as Amazon, Facebook,
Google and Microsoft, likely have significant advantages that would
reduce the prospect of inefficient outcomes due to ISP market power.
For example, the market capitalization of the smallest of these five
companies, Amazon, is more than twice that of the largest ISP, Comcast,
and the market capitalization of Google alone is greater than every
cable company in America combined. Action by these larger edge
providers preventing or reducing the use of ISP market power could
spill over to smaller edge providers, and in any case, is unlikely to
anticompetitively harm them given existing antitrust protections (since
arrangements between an ISP and a large established edge provider must
be consistent with antitrust law). Consequently, any market power even
the largest ISPs have over access to end users is limited in the extent
it can distort edge provider decisions (or those of their end users).
116. Despite the preceding analysis, a second claim is made that
relies solely on the second factor, single homing: ``regardless of the
competition in the local market for broadband internet access, once a
consumer chooses a broadband provider, that provider has a monopoly on
access to the subscriber . . . Once the broadband provider is the sole
provider of access to an end user, this can influence that network's
interactions with edge providers, end users, and others.'' Commenters
have echoed this ``terminating access monopoly'' concern. This argument
is often conflated with arguments about retail competition more
generally, but it is a distinct concept that has been endorsed by the
FCC and the courts in various contexts. The focus on edge providers'
bargaining position vis-[agrave]-vis ISPs is warranted in light of the
fact that any gatekeeper power applies to edge providers, not end
users. The Title II Order contended that these forces applied to all
ISPs, whether large or small, fixed or mobile, fiber or satellite, and
``therefore [it] need not consider whether market concentration gives
broadband providers the ability to raise prices.''
117. As a blanket statement, this position is not credible. It is
unlikely that any ISP, except the very largest, could exercise
substantial market power in negotiations with Google or Netflix, but
almost certainly no small wireless ISP, or a larger but still small
rural cable company or incumbent LEC, could do so. Further, from the
perspective of many edge providers, end users do not single home, but
subscribe to more than one platform (e.g., one fixed and one mobile)
capable of granting the end user effective access to the edge
provider's content (i.e., they multi-home). As the Title II Order
acknowledges, to the extent multihoming occurs in the use of an
application, there is no terminating monopoly.
118. Moreover, to the extent a terminating monopoly exists for some
edge providers, and it is not offset or more than offset by significant
advantages, there is the question of the extent to which the resulting
prices are economically inefficient. A terminating (access) monopoly
arises when customers on one side of the market, roughly speaking end
users in our case, single home with little prospect of switching to
another platform in the short run, while customers on the other side,
roughly speaking edge providers in our case, find it worthwhile to
multi-home. The terminating monopoly differs from conventional market
power because it can arise despite effective competition between
platforms. In that case, platforms must vigorously compete for single-
homing end users, but have less need to compete for edge providers, who
subscribe to all platforms. Such an arrangement is mutually
reinforcing. Single homers can reach all the multi-homers despite only
subscribing to one platform. Multi-homers must subscribe to all
platforms to reach all single homers. This means each ISP faces strong
pressures to cut prices to end users, but does not face similar
pressures in pricing to edge providers. However, ISPs are unlikely to
earn supranormal profits, so any markups earned from edge providers in
excess of total costs are generally passed through to end users. While
such an outcome generally will not be efficient, there is no general
presumption about the extent of that inefficiency, or even if prices to
the multi-homers ideally should be lower than would emerge in the
absence of a termination monopoly. In the present case, there is no
substantive evidence in the record that demonstrates how different
efficient prices to edge providers would be from the prices that would
emerge without rules banning paid prioritization or prohibiting ISPs
from charging providers at all.
119. Lastly, we find the record presents no compelling evidence
that any inefficiencies, to the extent they exist, justify Title II
regulation. There is no empirical evidence that the likely effects from
conventional market power or the terminating monopoly, to the extent
they exist, are likely to be significant, let alone outweigh the
harmful effects of Title II regulation. For all these reasons, we find
no case for supporting Title II regulation of ISP prices to edge
providers. We note that the terminating monopoly problem in voice
telecommunications is one created by common-carriage regulation, not
one solved by it. Specifically, carriers must interconnect with each
other and originating carriers must pay
[[Page 7878]]
terminating carriers rates set by the terminating carrier in their
tariff (with some government oversight). That leads to a ``bargaining''
situation where one party sets the terms of the deal and the other must
accept it or complain to the regulator--in other words, the regulations
prohibit a normal free market from developing. Such regulatory
requirements do not exist in broadband. Furthermore, two additional
aspects unique to the traditional telephone market created those
problems: (1) Voice call originators, who are (with the exception of
reverse charge calls) the analogue to edge providers in voice-
telecommunications, do not directly negotiate with the carrier that
sets call termination charges, but rather only have a relationship with
the call originating carrier. However, the originating carrier gains
from high call termination charges when it terminates calls on its own
network, so faces a conflict of interest when negotiating call
termination charges on behalf of its subscribers. In fact, such a
regime provides carriers with a mechanism for using the input price of
call termination to collude on retail prices. In contrast, edge
providers can directly connect with an ISP to reach that ISP's end
users, without seeking the ISP's help to terminate on another ISP's
network (unlike in voice telecommunications), or can use intermediaries
such as Cogent and Akamai, who largely do not terminate traffic to
their own end users, so do not face the conflict that voice carriers
face when negotiating termination charges. (2) Even if call originating
carriers had good incentives to negotiate reasonable termination
charges, regulation that requires interconnection, but does not
appropriately regulate termination charges, seriously weakens their
ability to obtain reasonable rates. Threatening to not interconnect is
not an available negotiating ploy in telecommunications, but is one
available to edge providers, especially larger ones, in negotiating
with ISPs. Moreover, historically voice telephony consisted of
geographic monopolies, making it pointless for one carrier to threaten
another with disconnection since the end users of the disconnected
carrier could not switch to a different carrier. Again, this is not
true for internet access.
120. Externalities Associated With General-Purpose Technologies Are
Not a Convincing Rationale for Title II Regulation. Some commenters
make somewhat inchoate arguments that ISPs should not be permitted to
treat different edge providers' content differently or charge more than
a zero price because the internet is a ``general purpose technology''
and/or the services of some edge providers create positive
externalities that the edge providers cannot appropriate. Hogendorn may
propose the most coherent version of this argument: Because the
internet is a general purpose technology (GPT), when an ISP sets a
price to any edge provider, the ISP does not take into account the
positive externalities generated by the broad (e.g., GPT) use of those
edge providers' applications (just as edge providers do not).
Unfortunately, these commentators fail to define or substantiate the
extent of the problem, if any; fail to demonstrate how much the
situation would be improved by requiring nondiscriminatory treatment of
all edge providers; do not explain why, if nondiscriminatory treatment
is required, it should be at a zero price; do not assess whether the
costs of such an intervention would be offset by the benefits; and do
not consider whether other less regulatory measures would be more
appropriate. For example, ISPs are one of many input suppliers to edge
providers, so taxing only ISPs would create distortions in edge
provider provision which could offset any (undemonstrated) benefits
such tax would bring. These problems are more acute if only specific
(as yet unidentified) edge providers generate positive externalities in
supply. Instead, these commenters seek to apply Title II regulation to
all ISPs, and consider the solution to their concern that certain
services or the internet itself might be inefficiently undersupplied
(for reasons well beyond the control of ISPs) to be a ban on ISPs only
(and not other input suppliers of edge providers) charging edge
providers any price. We reject this approach as unreasonable and
unreasoned.
3. Pre-Existing Consumer Protection and Competition Laws Protect the
Openness of the Internet
121. In the unlikely event that ISPs engage in conduct that harms
internet openness, despite the paucity of evidence of such incidents,
we find that utility-style regulation is unnecessary to address such
conduct. Other legal regimes--particularly antitrust law and the FTC's
authority under Section 5 of the FTC Act to prohibit unfair and
deceptive practices--provide protection for consumers. These long-
established and well-understood antitrust and consumer protection laws
are well-suited to addressing any openness concerns, because they apply
to the whole of the internet ecosystem, including edge providers,
thereby avoiding tilting the playing field against ISPs and causing
economic distortions by regulating only one side of business
transactions on the internet.
122. Consumer Protection. The FTC has broad authority to protect
consumers from ``unfair or deceptive acts or practices.'' As the
nation's premier consumer protection agency, the FTC has exercised its
authority, which arises from Section 5 of the FTC Act, to protect
consumers in all sectors of the economy. The FTC has used its Section 5
authority to enjoin some of the practices at issue in this proceeding,
such as throttling. The FTC is prohibited under the FTC Act from
regulating common carriers. As a result, the Commission's
classification of broadband internet access service as a common
carriage telecommunications service stripped the FTC of its authority
over ISPs. Therefore, as discussed in greater detail below, the return
to Title I will increase the FTC's effectiveness in protecting
consumers. Today's reclassification of broadband internet access
service restores the FTC's authority to enforce any commitments made by
ISPs regarding their network management practices that are included in
their advertising or terms and conditions, as the FTC did so
successfully in FTC v. TracFone. The FTC's unfair-and-deceptive-
practices authority ``prohibits companies from selling consumers one
product or service but providing them something different,'' which
makes voluntary commitments enforceable. The FTC also requires the
``disclos[ur]e [of] material information if not disclosing it would
mislead the consumer,'' so if an ISP ``failed to disclose blocking,
throttling, or other practices that would matter to a reasonable
consumer, the FTC's deception authority would apply.'' Today's
reclassification also restores the FTC's authority to take enforcement
action against unfair acts or practices. An unfair act or practice is
one that creates substantial consumer harm, is not outweighed by
countervailing benefits to consumers, and that consumers could not
reasonably have avoided. A unilateral change in a material term of a
contract can be an unfair practice. The FTC's 2007 Report on Broadband
Industry Practices raises the possibility that an ISP that starts
treating traffic from different edge providers differently without
notifying consumers and obtaining their consent may be engaging in a
practice that would be considered unfair under the FTC Act.
123. Many of the largest ISPs have committed in this proceeding not
to block or throttle legal content. These
[[Page 7879]]
commitments can be enforced by the FTC under Section 5, protecting
consumers without imposing public-utility regulation on ISPs. As
discussed below, we believe that case-by-case, ex post regulation
better serves a dynamic industry like the internet and reduces the risk
of over-regulation. We also reject assertions that the FTC has
insufficient authority, because, as Verizon argues, ``[i]f broadband
service providers' conduct falls outside [the FTC's] grant of
jurisdiction--that is, if their actions cannot be described as
anticompetitive, unfair, or deceptive--then the conduct should not be
banned in the first place.'' In addition to rejecting claims that the
FTC's authority is insufficient, we also reject arguments that it lacks
the necessary expertise to protect consumers in this area. The comments
by the FTC's Acting Chairman in this proceeding persuade us of that
agency's understanding of the issues and of its ability to resume
oversight of ISP practices. Just as importantly, any loss of expertise
is outweighed by the benefits of having a single expert consumer
protection agency overseeing the entire internet ecosystem. We
anticipate sharing information and expertise with the FTC as we work
together to protect consumers under the framework adopted today. And
the transparency rule that we adopt today should allay any concerns
about the ambiguity of ISP commitments, by requiring ISPs to disclose
if the ISPs block or throttle legal content. For the same reasons, the
transparency rule allows us to reject the argument that antitrust and
consumer protection enforcers cannot detect problematic conduct.
Finally, we expect that any attempt by ISPs to undermine the openness
of the internet would be resisted by consumers and edge providers. We
also observe that all states have laws proscribing deceptive trade
practices.
124. Antitrust. The antitrust laws, particularly Sections 1 and 2
of the Sherman Act, as well as Section 5 of the FTC Act, protect
competition in all sectors of the economy where the antitrust agencies
have jurisdiction. When challenged as anticompetitive under the
antitrust laws, the types of conduct and practices prohibited under the
Title II Order would likely be evaluated under the ``rule of reason,''
which amounts to a consumer welfare test. The Communications Act
includes an antitrust savings clause, so the antitrust laws apply with
equal vigor to entities regulated by the Commission. Should the
hypothetical anticompetitive harms that proponents of Title II imagine
eventually come to pass, application of the antitrust laws would
address those harms.
125. Section 1 of the Sherman Act bars contracts, combinations, or
conspiracies in restraint of trade, making anticompetitive arrangements
illegal. If ISPs reached horizontal agreements to unfairly block,
throttle, or discriminate against internet conduct or applications,
these agreements likely would be per se illegal under the antitrust
laws. EFF argues that the single entity doctrine means that a
vertically-integrated ISP could collude with its affiliated content arm
without fear of the antitrust laws. This argument is inapposite,
however, because such a claim against a vertically-integrated ISP would
likely be based on Section 2 of the Sherman Act under an attempted
monopolization theory, rather than as a Section 1 collusion claim.
Section 2 of the Sherman Act, which applies if a firm possesses or has
a dangerous probability of achieving monopoly power, prohibits
exclusionary conduct, which can include refusals to deal and exclusive
dealing, tying arrangements, and vertical restraints. Section 2 makes
it unlawful for a vertically integrated ISP to anticompetitively favor
its content or services over unaffiliated edge providers' content or
services. Treble damages are available under both Section 1 and Section
2. We note that FTC enforcement of Section 5 is broader and would apply
in the absence of monopoly power.
126. Most of the examples of net neutrality violations discussed in
the Title II Order could have been investigated as antitrust
violations. Madison River Communications blocked access to VoIP to
foreclose competition to its telephony business; an antitrust case
would have focused on whether the company was engaged in
anticompetitive foreclosure to preserve any monopoly power it may have
had over telephony. Whether one regards Comcast's behavior toward
BitTorrent as blocking or throttling, it could have been pursued either
as an antitrust or consumer protection case. The Commission noted that
BitTorrent's service allowed users to view video that they might
otherwise have to purchase through Comcast's Video on Demand service--a
claim that could be considered an anticompetitive foreclosure claim
under antitrust. Comcast also failed to disclose this network
management practice and initially denied that it was engaged in any
throttling--potentially unfair or deceptive acts or practices. If an
ISP that also sells video services degrades the speed or quality of
competing ``Over the Top'' video services (such as Netflix), that
conduct could be challenged as anticompetitive foreclosure.
127. Among the benefits of the antitrust laws over public utility
regulation are (1) the rule of reason allows a balancing of pro-
competitive benefits and anti-competitive harms; (2) the case-by-case
nature of antitrust allows for the regulatory humility needed when
dealing with the dynamic internet; (3) the antitrust laws focus on
protecting competition; and (4) the same long-practiced and well-
understood laws apply to all internet actors.
128. Reasonableness. The unilateral conduct that is covered by
Section 2 of the Sherman Act would be evaluated under a standard
similar to the rule of reason applicable to conduct governed by Section
1, ``an all-encompassing inquiry, paying close attention to the
consumer benefits and downsides of the challenged practice based on the
facts at hand.'' We believe that such an inquiry will strike a better
balance in protecting the openness of the internet and continuing to
allow the ``permissionless innovation'' that made the internet such an
important part of the modern U.S. economy, as antitrust uses a welfare
standard defined by economic analysis shaped by a significant body of
precedent. Compare this to the Internet Conduct Standard, which would
examine a variety of considerations broader than consumer welfare, as
well as factors yet to be determined.
129. The case-by-case, content-specific analysis established by the
rule of reason will allow new innovative business arrangements to
emerge as part of the ever-evolving internet ecosystem. New
arrangements that harm consumers and weaken competition will run afoul
of the Sherman Act, and successful plaintiffs will receive treble
damages. The FTC and DOJ can also bring enforcement actions in
situations where private plaintiffs are unable or unwilling to do so.
New arrangements benefiting consumers, like so many internet
innovations over the last generation, will be allowed to continue, as
was the case before the imposition of Title II utility-style regulation
of ISPs.
130. We reject commenters' assertions that the case-by-case nature
of antitrust enforcement makes it inherently flawed. A case-by-case
approach minimizes the costs of overregulation, including tarring all
ISPs with the same brush, and reduces the risk of false positives when
regulation is necessary. We believe the Commission's bright-line and
internet conduct rules are more likely to inhibit innovation before it
occurs, whereas antitrust enforcement can adequately remedy harms
should they occur. As
[[Page 7880]]
such, we reject the argument that innovation is best protected by ex
ante rules and command-and-control government regulation. Further,
while a handful of ISPs are large and vertically integrated with
content producers, most ISPs are small companies that have no leverage
in negotiations with large edge providers, which include some of the
most valuable companies in the world. Regulating these companies is
unnecessarily harmful. The antitrust laws can be tailored to the ISP's
circumstances. We reject as fundamentally speculative claims that
significantly different behavior is likely from entities that were
subject to antitrust suits, as compared to those that have not yet
been--but still could be--subject to such suits, or based on the theory
that antitrust authorities are likely to negotiate materially different
resolutions even for similarly situated entities or circumstances.
131. Moreover, the case-by-case analysis, coupled with the rule of
reason, allows for innovative arrangements to be evaluated based on
their real-world effects, rather than a regulator's ex ante
predictions. Such an approach better fits the dynamic internet economy
than the top-down mandates imposed by Title II. Further, the antitrust
laws recognize the importance of protecting innovation. Indeed, the FTC
has pursued several cases in recent years where its theory of harm was
decreased innovation. Accordingly, we believe that antitrust law can
sufficiently protect innovation, which is a matter of particular
importance for the continued development of the internet. Some
commenters argue that antitrust law is more limited in scope than the
rules in the Title II Order, antitrust enforcement necessarily takes
place after some harm has already occurred, and proving an antitrust
violation can be expensive and time-consuming. However, with a body of
established and evolving precedent, the FTC's antitrust enforcement is
fact-based, flexible and applicable to internet-related markets before
the Title II Order. We find that the antitrust framework will strike a
better balance by protecting competition and consumers while providing
industry with greater regulatory certainty. We also find that the
combination of the transparency rule, ISP commitments, and their
enforcement by the FTC sufficiently address the argument made by
several commenters that antitrust moves too slowly and is too expensive
for many supposed beneficiaries of regulation.
132. Additionally, the existence of antitrust law deters much
potential anticompetitive conduct before it occurs, and where it occurs
offers recoupment through damages to harmed competitors. Some
commenters have cast doubt on the effectiveness of ex post enforcement,
preferring ex ante rules. Yet as the FTC staff noted in its comments,
this is a false dichotomy. ``Effective rule of law requires both
appropriate standards--whether established by common law court,
Congress in statute, or by an agency in rules--and active enforcement
of those standards.'' Even the ``bright line'' rules in the Title II
Order contain an exception for ``reasonable network management.'' An
ISP accused of violating those rules would be the subject of an ex post
FCC enforcement action. The FCC would have to determine ex post whether
a challenged practice constituted technical network management or not.
133. Moreover, economic research has demonstrated that the threat
of antitrust enforcement deters anticompetitive actions. Block et al.
find that an increase in the likelihood of antitrust enforcement in the
U.S. has a significant effect on lowering prices to consumers.
Similarly it has been found that countries with vigorous antitrust
statutes and enforcement, such as the United States, reduce the effects
of anticompetitive behavior when it does occur. There is also evidence
that firms, once they have been subject to an enforcement action, are
less likely to violate the antitrust laws in the future. Overall, we
have confidence that the use of antitrust enforcement to protect
competition in the broadband internet service provider market will
ensure that consumers continue to reap the benefits of that
competition. We conclude that the light-touch approach that we adopt
today, in combination with existing antitrust and consumer protection
laws, more than adequately addresses concerns about internet openness,
particularly as compared to the rigidity of Title II. Some commenters
have raised issues about the feasibility of antitrust as applied to
some potential harms. CompTIA and OTI claim that the unilateral refusal
to deal and essential facilities cases are more difficult to bring
after Verizon Commc'ns, Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, 540
U.S. 398 (2004) and Pacific Bell Tel. Co. v. linkLine Commc'ns, Inc.,
555 U.S. 438 (2009). To the extent these commenters are correct, the
transparency rule and FTC enforcement of the commitments (based on
Section 5 of the FTC's Act broader reach than antitrust) remain to
protect the openness of the internet, and the shifts in antitrust
doctrine do not support the imposition of Title II.
134. Focus on protecting competition. One of the benefits of
antitrust law is its strong focus on protecting competition and
consumers. If a particular practice benefits consumers, antitrust law
will not condemn it. The fact that antitrust law protects competition
means that it also protects other qualities that consumers value.
``[The] assumption that competition is the best method of allocating
resources in a free market recognizes that all elements of a bargain--
quality, service, safety, and durability--and not just the immediate
cost, are favorably affected by the free opportunity to select among
alternative offers.'' The market competition that antitrust law
preserves will protect values such as free expression, to the extent
that consumers value free expression as a service attribute and are
aware of how their ISPs' actions affect free expression. The lack of
evidence of harms to free expression on the internet also bolsters our
belief that Title II is unnecessary to protect social values that are
not the focus of antitrust. The anecdotes of harms to internet openness
cited by supporters of the Title II Order almost exclusively concern
business decisions regarding network management, rather than being
aimed at or impacting political expression. In any case, the
transparency rule and the ISP commitments backed up by FTC enforcement
are targeted to preserving free expression, particularly the no-
blocking commitment. Therefore, we believe that the argument that
antitrust law does not consider non-economic factors such as free
expression and diversity fails to support Title II regulation.
135. Finally, applying antitrust principles to ISP conduct is
consistent with longstanding economic and legal principles that cover
all sectors of the economy, including the entire internet ecosystem.
Applying the same body of law to ISPs, edge providers, and all internet
actors avoids the regulatory distortions of Title II, which ``impos[ed]
asymmetric behavioral regulations . . . on broadband ISPs under the
banner of protecting internet openness, but le[ft] internet edge
providers free to threaten or engage in the same types of behavior
prohibited to ISPs free of any ex ante constraints.'' Our decision
today to return to light-touch Title I regulation and the backstop of
generally-applicable antitrust and consumer protection law ``help[s] to
ensure a level, technology-neutral playing field'' for the whole
internet.
[[Page 7881]]
D. Restoring the Information Service Classification Is Lawful and
Necessary
136. The Commission has the legal authority to return to the
classification of broadband internet access service as an ``information
service.'' The Supreme Court made clear when affirming the Commission's
original information service classification of cable modem service that
Congress ``delegated to the Commission authority to execute and enforce
the Communications Act, as well as prescribe the rules and regulations
necessary in the public interest to carry out the provisions.'' This
delegation includes the legal authority to interpret the definitional
provisions of the Communications Act. Nothing in the record
meaningfully contests this fundamental point. Relying on that
authority, we change course from the Title II Order and restore the
information service classification of broadband internet access
service, which represents the best interpretation of the Act. We reject
arguments against reclassification based on alleged shortcomings in the
justification for changing course provided in the Internet Freedom NPRM
given that we fully explain here our rationale for revisiting the Title
II Order's classification of broadband internet access service. As
discussed above, this action is supported by the text, structure, and
history of the Act, the nature of ISP offerings, judicial and
Commission precedent, and the public policy consequences flowing from
reclassification. For this reason, and for those set forth more fully
in Section III above, we reject claims that an information service
classification is unambiguously precluded. Such assertions are contrary
to our interpretation of the statutory language and our application of
it to the facts before us and also find no support in the relevant
court precedent addressing prior classification decisions, which either
affirmed an information service classification or affirmed the recent
telecommunications service classification as merely a permissible
interpretation of ambiguous statutory language. In making these
arguments, commenters do not dispute the Commission's general authority
to interpret and apply the Act, but merely present arguments regarding
the reasonableness or permissibility of interpreting or applying the
Act in particular ways.
137. An agency of course may decide to change course, and such a
decision is not, as some commenters suggest, inherently suspect. The
Supreme Court has observed that there is ``no basis in the
Administrative Procedure Act or in our opinions for a requirement that
all agency change be subjected to more searching review. . . . [I]t
suffices that the new policy is permissible under the statute, that
there are good reasons for it, and that the agency believes it to be
better, which the conscious change of course adequately indicates.''
Relevant precedent holds that we need only ``examine the relevant data
and articulate a satisfactory explanation for [our] action,'' a duty we
fully satisfy here. The ``possibility of drawing two inconsistent
conclusions from the evidence does not prevent an administrative
agency's finding from being supported by substantial evidence.'' As
such, we reject arguments that reclassification must be premised on
changed factual circumstances or preceded by a significant gap in time.
Rather, we are ``entitled to assess administrative records and evaluate
priorities'' in light of our current policy judgments. As the Court
recognized in Brand X, ``in Chevron itself, the Court deferred to an
agency interpretation that was a recent reversal of agency policy.''
The USTelecom decision supports our understanding of the relevant legal
standard, affirming the Title II Order's reclassification of broadband
internet access service irrespective of whether any facts had changed.
138. Such a change in course can be justified on a variety of
possible grounds. The Supreme Court observed in Brand X that ``the
agency . . . must consider varying interpretations and the wisdom of
its policy on a continuing basis, for example in response to . . . a
change in administrations.'' In addition, if an agency's predictions
``prove erroneous, the Commission will need to reconsider'' the
associated regulatory actions ``in accordance with its continuing
obligation to practice reasoned decision-making.'' In short, the
Commission's reasoned determination today that classifying broadband
internet access service as an information service is superior both as a
matter of textual interpretation and public policy suffices to support
the change in direction--even absent any new facts or changes in
circumstances. But even assuming such new facts were necessary, the
record provides several other sufficient and independent bases for our
decision to revisit the classification of broadband internet access
service.
139. For example, we find that the Title II Order's regulatory
predictions have not been borne out. Although purporting to adopt a
`light-touch' regulatory framework for broadband internet access
service, this view of the Title II Order's action faced skepticism at
the time, and we find those concerns confirmed in practice. For
example, the Wireless Telecommunications Bureau initiated inquiries
into wireless ISPs' sponsored data and zero-rated offerings, leading to
a report casting doubt on the legality of certain types of such
offerings. That report was later retracted. And the Commission
proceeded, in the wake of the reclassification in the Title II Order,
to adopt complex and highly prescriptive privacy regulations for
broadband internet access service, which ultimately were disapproved by
Congress under the Congressional Review Act. The amorphous and
potentially wide-ranging implications of the Title II-based regulatory
framework have hindered (or will likely hinder) marketplace innovation,
as the record here indicates and as one logically would expect. We thus
reject the suggestion that the Title II Order yielded ``legal and
economic certainty.'' That certain specific steps eventually were
rolled back is no cure--rather, those initial actions provide cause for
significant concerns that the regulatory framework adopted in the Title
II Order would be anything but ``light-touch'' over time. Given the
evidence that the Title II-based framework prompted additional
regulatory action and was not living up to its ``light-touch'' label,
we disagree with claims that ``[t]here has been no material change of
circumstance since the adoption of the'' Title II Order, or that the
shortcomings inherent in the Title II approach could be addressed
adequately through minor adjustments to the rules adopted in the Title
II Order.
140. Further, we are not persuaded that there were reasonable
reliance interests in the Title II Order that preclude our revisiting
the classification of broadband internet access service. Contrary to
Twilio's assertion that bright-line rules are over a decade old, we
note that the Commission did not establish any rules until 2010--just
seven years ago--and did not establish enforceable bright-line rules
until 2015--just two years ago. Assertions in the record regarding
absolute levels of edge investment do not meaningfully attempt to
attribute particular portions of that investment to any reliance on the
Title II Order. Nor are we persuaded that such reliance would have been
reasonable in any event, given the lengthy prior history of information
service classification of broadband internet access service, which we
are simply restoring here after the brief
[[Page 7882]]
period of departure initiated by the Title II Order.
141. ``[A]n agency literally has no power to act . . . unless and
until Congress confers power upon it.'' And so our role is to achieve
the outcomes Congress instructs, invoking the authorities that Congress
has given us--not to assume that Congress must have given us authority
to address any problems the Commission identifies. However, rather than
looking to Congress to address its statutory authority after the 2010
Comcast decision, the Commission instead attempted increasingly-
regulatory approaches under existing statutory provisions, culminating
in the Title II Order's application of a legal regime that was ill-
suited for broadband internet access service. Returning to the
Commission's historically sound approach to interpreting and applying
the Act to broadband internet access service corrects what we see as
shortcomings in how the Commission, in the recent past, conceptualized
its role in this context.
142. We also conclude that the Commission should have been
cautioned against reclassifying broadband internet access service as a
telecommunications service in 2015 because doing so involved ``laying
claim to extravagant statutory power over the national economy while at
the same time strenuously asserting that the authority claimed would
render the statute `unrecognizable to the Congress that designed' it.''
Such interpretations ``typically [are] greet[ed] . . . with a measure
of skepticism'' by courts, and we believe they should be by the
Commission, as well. We rely on these principles to inform what
interpretation constitutes the best reading of the Act independent of
any broader legal implications that potentially could result from such
considerations. Thus, although the separate opinions in the denial of
rehearing en banc in USTelecom debated the application of such
principles here--including with respect to issues of agency deference
and the permissibility of the Commission's prior classification--we
need not and do not reach such broader issues. As relevant here, the DC
Circuit in Verizon observed that ``regulation of broadband internet
providers''--there, rules that required per se common carriage--
``certainly involves decisions of great `economic and political
significance.' '' That seems at least as apt a description of the Title
II Order decision classifying broadband internet access service as a
common carrier telecommunications as one adopting rules compelling the
service to be offered in a manner that is per se common carriage. In
particular, the Title II Order recognized that classification of
broadband internet access service as a telecommunications service
would, absent forbearance, subject the service and its providers to a
panoply of duties and requirements ill-suited to broadband internet
access service. Thus, not only did reclassification involve what we see
as a claim of extravagant statutory power, but the Commission found
that much of the resulting power was not sensibly applied to broadband
internet access service--a view we believe also would be held by
Congress itself. Restoring the information service classification that
applied for nearly two decades before the Title II Order does not
require any claim by the Commission of extravagant statutory power over
broadband internet access service and eliminates the anomaly that ill-
fitting Title II regulation would apply by default to broadband
internet access service. These considerations thus lend support to our
decision to reclassify broadband internet access service as an
information service.
E. Effects on Regulatory Structures Created by the Title II Order
143. In this section, we clarify the regulatory effects of today's
reinstatement of broadband internet access service as a Title I
``information service'' on other regulatory frameworks affected or
imposed by the Title II Order, including the effects on: (1) Internet
traffic exchange arrangements; (2) the Title II Order's forbearance
framework; (3) privacy; (4) wireline broadband infrastructure; (5)
wireless broadband infrastructure; (6) universal service; (7)
jurisdiction and preemption; and (8) disability access. We do not
intend for today's classification to affect ISPs' obligations under the
Communications Assistance for Law Enforcement Act, the Foreign
Intelligence Surveillance Act, or the Electronic Communications Privacy
Act. No commenter identifies any such effect of reclassification, nor
does such a change appear to have justified the classification decision
in the Title II Order. We also are not persuaded that our
classification decision will itself have material negative consequences
as it relates to safe harbor protections for ISPs under the Digital
Millennium Copyright Act (DMCA). Our actions here return to the
analysis in Brand X and other pre-2015 classification decisions and the
associated successful regulatory framework, and we are not persuaded
that the DMCA would apply materially differently now so as to render
the regulatory framework for broadband internet access service less
successful today.
1. Ending Title II Regulation of Internet Traffic Exchange
144. The Title II Order applied, for the first time, the
requirements of Title II to internet traffic exchange ``by an edge
provider . . . with the broadband provider's network.'' OTI's argument
that internet traffic exchange was not classified as a Title II service
is unpersuasive. The Title II Order did not subject internet traffic
exchange to Title II obligations but, as OTI acknowledges, interpreted
broadband internet access services to include internet traffic exchange
between an ISP and an edge provider or its transit provider as ``a
portion'' of the service, or alternatively as used ``for and in
connection with'' that service. In doing so, the Title II Order applied
certain Title II requirements to these internet traffic exchange
arrangements. We make clear that as a result of our decision to restore
the longstanding classification of broadband internet access service as
an information service, internet traffic exchange arrangements are no
longer subject to Title II and its attendant obligations. We thus
return internet traffic exchange to the longstanding free market
framework under which the internet grew and flourished for decades.
145. Background. As the Title II Order acknowledges, the market for
internet traffic exchange between ISPs and edge providers or their
intermediaries ``historically has functioned without significant
Commission oversight.'' We disagree with assertions that withdrawing
from regulation of interconnection agreements would represent a break
with longstanding Commission precedent. The Commission made clear in
the Open Internet Order that it did not intend the open internet rules
``to affect existing arrangements for network interconnections,
including existing paid peering arrangements.'' For many years, both
ISPs and edge providers largely paid third-party backbone service
providers for transit, and backbone providers connected upstream until
they reached Tier 1 backbone service providers which provided access to
the full internet. In recent years, particularly with the rise of
online video, edge providers increasingly used CDNs and direct
interconnection with ISPs, rather than transit, to increase the quality
of their service. At the same time, ISPs have increasingly built or
acquired their own backbone services, allowing them to interconnect
with
[[Page 7883]]
other networks without paying for third-party transit services.
146. Notwithstanding these developments, but in line with other
aspects of the Title II Order seeking to extend the Commission's
regulatory authority, the Commission seized on a handful of anecdotes
to extend utility-style regulation to internet traffic exchange
arrangements. The Title II Order applied eight different sections of
Title II, including Sections 201, 202, and 208, to traffic exchange
between ISPs and edge providers or their intermediaries. We reject the
argument that this application of Title II, which includes potential
Commission mandates ``to establish physical connections with other
carriers, to establish through routes and charges applicable thereto
and the divisions of such charges, and to establish and provide
facilities and regulations for operating such through routes,'' was
light-touch, measured regulation. Although the Title II Order did not
apply the bright-line rules to internet traffic exchange, it stated
that the Commission would be ``available to hear disputes regarding
arrangements for the exchange of traffic with a broadband internet
access provider raised under Sections 201 and 202 on a case-by-case
basis.'' The Commission did not articulate specific criteria that it
would apply when hearing such disputes.
147. Deregulating Internet Traffic Exchange. Today, we return to
the pre-Title II Order status quo by classifying broadband internet
access service as an information service and, in doing so, reverse that
Order's extension of Title II authority to internet traffic exchange
arrangements. As was the case before the Title II Order, we retain
subject-matter jurisdiction over internet traffic exchange under Title
I, to the extent such exchange arrangements are ``wire'' or ``radio
communications.'' There is no dispute that ISPs, backbone transit
providers, and large edge providers are sophisticated, well-capitalized
businesses. Indeed, the Title II Order acknowledged as much, and
refused to impose ``prescriptive rules'' or even ``draw policy
conclusions concerning new paid internet traffic arrangements.''
Notwithstanding these acknowledgments, the Title II Order cast a shadow
on new arrangements in this sector by applying a range of common
carrier requirements to internet traffic exchange.
148. We believe that applying Title II to internet traffic exchange
arrangements was unnecessary and is likely to unduly inhibit
competition and innovation. As the court in USTelecom observed, the
Title II Order's oversight of interconnection was premised on the
concern that ISPs could evade the restrictions imposed via regulation
of the ``last mile'' through actions taken in connection with internet
interconnection arrangements. Here, however, we conclude that Title II
regulation and conduct rules are not warranted even as to the ``last
mile.'' The Title II Order itself recognized that the need for
intervention in matters of internet interconnection was less certain
than its conclusions regarding ISP actions in the ``last mile.''
Against that backdrop, along with our finding that Commission
regulation of ISP conduct in the ``last mile'' is unwarranted, we see
no grounds for finding that Title II regulation of internet traffic
exchange is necessary here. And absent Title II as a hook for
regulation of internet traffic exchange, we can identify no other
source of statutory authority to impose market-wide prophylactic
regulation on these arrangements. To the extent we have previously
proposed conditions on internet traffic exchange activities in the
context of specific mergers, those conditions were based on the
circumstances of specific entities in specific transactions and were
agreed to by those entities to facilitate a proposed merger. Those
conditions were not, however, predicated on any statutory provision
giving the Commission general authority to engage in prophylactic
regulation of all interconnection arrangements.
149. Instead, we find that freeing internet traffic exchange
arrangements from burdensome government regulation, and allowing market
forces to discipline this emerging and competitive market is the better
course. It is telling that, in the absence of Title II regulation, the
cost of internet transit fell over 99 percent on a cost-per-megabit
basis from 2005 to 2015. We do not rely on transit pricing alone, but
consider it in combination with the other factors discussed in this
section, and thus reject as inapposite claims that transit pricing
alone is an inadequate way of evaluating internet traffic exchange.
Further, we find that even those commenters that insist that ISPs wield
undue power in the interconnection market have offered no evidence that
ISPs generally charge supra-competitive prices for internet traffic
exchange arrangements. Moreover, we reject the proposition that prior
examples of settlement-free peering necessarily mean that a transit
price above zero is inherently anti- or supra-competitive. While the
move to paid peering may affect the bottom line of Tier 1 transit
providers, those effects cannot justify ex ante regulation unless they
are anti-competitive and harm end users. The record is devoid of
evidence of consumer harm in this regard since the resolution of the
Netflix congestion issues in 2014. Indeed, the new case-by-case dispute
process has gone unused, even as OVDs--which ISPs presumably might view
as competitors to affiliated video programming products or services--
have proliferated. Moreover, contrary to these unsubstantiated claims
of harm, we find that there are substantial pro-competitive and pro-
consumer benefits to alternative internet traffic exchange
arrangements. Because we conclude that this is the wiser course, we
reject comments asserting that a dispute resolution process is needed.
150. We welcome the growth of alternative internet traffic exchange
arrangements, including direct interconnection, CDNs, and other
innovative efforts. All parties appear to agree that direct
interconnection has benefited consumers by reducing congestion,
increasing speeds, and housing content closer to consumers, and allowed
ISPs to better manage their networks. CDNs play a similar role. We
believe that market dynamics, not Title II regulation, allowed these
diverse arrangements to thrive. Our decision to reclassify broadband
internet access service as an information service, and to remove Title
II utility-style regulation from internet traffic exchange, will spur
further investment and innovation in this market. Returning to the pre-
Title II Order light-touch framework will also eliminate the
asymmetrical regulatory treatment of parties to internet traffic
exchange arrangements. As NTCA explains, the Title II Order imposed a
one-sided interconnection duty upon last-mile ISPs--even though,
especially in rural areas, ``many ISPs are a tiny fraction of the size
of upstream middle mile and transit networks or content and edge
providers.'' The record reflects that the asymmetric regulation imposed
under the Title II Order unjustifiably provided edge providers, many of
whom are sophisticated entities with significant market power due to
high demand for their content, with additional leverage in negotiating
interconnection. We anticipate that eliminating one-sided regulation of
internet traffic exchange and restoring regulatory parity among
sophisticated commercial entities will allow the parties to more
efficiently negotiate mutually-acceptable arrangements to meet end user
demands for network usage.
151. We find that present competitive pressures in the market for
internet
[[Page 7884]]
traffic exchange mitigate the risk that an ISP might block or degrade
edge provider traffic through arrangements for internet traffic
exchange sufficiently to undermine the need for regulatory oversight
through Title II regulation. We thus disagree with generalized
assertions by some commenters to the contrary. In drawing this
conclusion, we recognize that the Commission previously imposed
internet interconnection conditions in the AT&T/DirecTV Order and
Charter/TWC Order to address claimed risks that the merged entity could
use internet interconnection to disadvantage rivals, particularly
competing providers of over-the-top video services. We decline to draw
judgments about the nature of the market as a whole from individual
determinations made in the context of particular merger orders. As an
initial matter, the Commission made these determinations pursuant to
its authority to impose conditions on transfers of licenses or
authorizations. As noted above, the Commission has identified no
broader general authority to impose these conditions on the
interconnection market as a whole. In addition, those orders were based
on an analysis of specific issues raised in those adjudications and
application of a public-interest statutory standard that differs from
the competition-based standard applied by the Department of Justice's
Antitrust Division during merger review. Further, those orders were
based on a narrowly-focused analysis of specific issues raised in those
adjudications. As we explain above, based on the record here, we
decline to repeat that finding of high switching costs. Finally,
because those orders were adopted without the benefit of notice-and-
comment rulemaking, we decline to make general inferences from
conditions contained in such documents, when the voluminous record
submitted in this proceeding persuades us that the interconnection
market is competitive. We thus are unpersuaded that the actions taken
in the AT&T/DirecTV Order and Charter/TWC Order should guide our
decisions here. Interconnection concerns generally focus on the
possibility that an ISP could block or allow congestion on paths used
to deliver traffic to that ISP as a way of harming rivals or extracting
unreasonable payments associated with that interconnection. Edge
providers have a variety of options in deciding how to deliver their
content to ISPs, including a large number of transit providers, CDNs,
and direct interconnection. Edge providers also can shift the path for
their traffic in response to congestion in real time. To address the
possibility that edge providers could simply shift their traffic away
from a blocked or congested path, it appears in most cases that the ISP
would need to engage in blocking or allow congestion on essentially all
paths to its network, affecting all traffic to and from the ISP's
customers. To the extent that some theorize that an ISP might harm
rivals with particularly high volumes of internet traffic through
actions taken with respect to a smaller number of interconnection
paths, we are not persuaded that such large providers of internet
traffic would lack sufficient leverage to achieve a reasonable
marketplace resolution, particularly given the increased likelihood
that such a large source of internet traffic would be highly valued by
end-users with which it could communicate directly regarding any
interconnection dispute. In addition, although certain forms of traffic
might be particularly sensitive to the quality of interconnection such
that some alternative interconnection paths would be inferior, it is
likely that blocking or allowing degradation of a substantial number of
paths to the ISP still would be necessary for such conduct to
effectively impact such traffic given that the concerns in the record
center on large ISPs, that are more likely than small ISPs to have
multiple viable interconnection paths. Further, that is but one of many
considerations that would affect the relative incentives and
marketplace leverage of the relevant ISP and interconnecting network
and/or edge provider. The practical viability of such a strategy thus
depends in general on an ISP's willingness to undermine the performance
of all or virtually all internet traffic to and from its customers. An
ISP's incentive to take such a step would involve a complex marketplace
evaluation requiring it to account for the associated risk of customer
dissatisfaction. Although this consideration alone does not necessarily
guarantee that no ISP ever would engage in such conduct, we reject
interconnection-related concerns that fail to meaningfully grapple with
this factor. Further, this factor must be considered in conjunction
with the overlay of legal protections, such as antitrust and consumer
protection laws discussed below. We find that these marketplace
dynamics are likely to impede, if not preclude, any effort by an ISP to
harm a specific edge provider's traffic.
152. Insofar as certain commenters contend that incidents such as
Cogent's experience delivering Netflix traffic in 2014 suggest
otherwise, we note that the origin of the Cogent-Netflix congestion is
disputed and that Cogent admitted to de-prioritizing certain types of
traffic for the congestion. In any event, there is ample evidence that
major edge providers, including Netflix, YouTube, and other large OVDs,
are some of the ``most-loved'' brands in the world. Their reputations
and the importance of reputation to their business and brand gives them
significant incentive to inform consumers and work to shape consumer
perceptions in the event of any dispute with ISPs. This incentive
mitigates potential concerns that consumers lack the knowledge and
ability to hold their ISPs accountable for interconnection disputes.
Further, as NCTA explains, ``the edge providers that send enough
traffic to impact interconnection--e.g., Netflix, Google/YouTube,
Facebook, and Amazon--are entities critical for a broadband provider to
meet its customers' needs.'' As another commenter explains, edge
providers, including OVDs, are complementary to ISPs' broadband
business, and reducing the value of these complementary products would
harm ISPs by reducing demand for their services. For all of these
reasons, we find that market dynamics are likely to mitigate the risk
that ISPs will block, degrade, or deprioritize specific edge providers'
traffic.
153. In addition, if an ISP attempts to block or degrade traffic in
a manner that is anti-competitive, such conduct may give rise to
actions by federal or state agencies under antitrust or consumer
protection laws. Some commenters have called for continued ex post
regulation of internet traffic exchange between ISPs and transit or
edge providers, potentially under Title I, or disclosure requirements.
For the reasons discussed here, we reject these arguments. As to
antitrust laws, antitrust authorities are empowered to police anti-
competitive conduct by ISPs (conduct that would be particularly salient
in cases where ISP competition was limited or nonexistent). We reject
the argument that the Commission's decision in the Charter-Time Warner
Cable Merger Order compels us to apply Title II regulation to
interconnection for the reasons discussed herein, infra Part VI.A. In
addition, the backstop of generally-applicable consumer protection laws
continues to protect consumers and edge providers. These laws,
particularly antitrust laws which prevent certain refusals to deal,
will also protect small, rural ISPs which may face difficulties
interconnecting with edge providers, transit providers, and larger
[[Page 7885]]
ISPs. Accordingly, assertions that public-utility regulation of
internet traffic exchange arrangements is necessary to allow consumers
to reach content of their choice are unpersuasive.
154. Even assuming that economic incentives and antitrust and
consumer protection remedies may not prevent or redress all potential
harms in the interconnection market, we find the regulatory approach
adopted in the Title II Order fatally overbroad as it relates to the
interconnection concerns identified in the record here. The Title II
Order's legal basis for oversight of interconnection depended on the
definition of broadband internet access service to include traffic
exchange and the classification of that entire service as a
telecommunications service subject to Title II--a classification that
applied to all ISPs, regardless of size or other characteristics. Here,
however, we have already rejected the Title II Order's rationales for
Title II regulation and explained the harms that flow from that regime.
The record reveals that retaining the Title II Order approach to
interconnection would be overbroad in other ways, as well. The
classification decision in that Order applied to all ISPs regardless of
size, while the concerns about ISPs in the record here center on a few
of the largest ISPs. The Title II Order classification also applied
irrespective of the specific traffic being carried, while some
advocates of interconnection oversight here express particular concerns
about certain subsets of traffic, like video traffic. Particularly
given the marketplace complexities associated with whether a given ISP
would, in fact, engage in harmful conduct, we are not persuaded that
the inchoate interconnection concerns identified in the record here
would justify retaining the Title II Order's approach to
interconnection with its sweeping, preemptive--and harmful--resulting
consequences.
2. Forbearance
155. As we have reinstated the information service classification
of broadband internet access service, the forbearance granted in the
Title II Order is now moot. We return to the pre-Title II Order status
quo and allow providers voluntarily electing to offer broadband
transmission on a common carrier basis to do so under the frameworks
established in the Wireline Broadband Classification Order and the
Wireless Broadband Internet Access Order. We also clarify that carriers
are no longer permitted to use the Title II Order forbearance framework
(i.e., no carrier will be permitted to maintain, or newly elect, the
Title II Order forbearance framework).
156. Prior to the Title II Order, some facilities-based wireline
carriers chose to offer broadband transmission services on a common
carrier basis subject to the full range of Title II requirements. In
the 2005 Wireline Broadband Classification Order, the Commission ruled
that broadband internet access was an information service, but at the
same time permitted facilities-based wireline carriers to voluntarily
elect to offer the transmission component of broadband internet access
service (often referred to as digital subscriber line or DSL) on a
common carrier basis. Operators choosing to offer broadband
transmission on a common carriage basis could do so under tariff or
could use non-tariff arrangements. The Commission permitted facilities-
based carriers to choose whether to offer wireline broadband internet
access transmission as non-common carriage or common carriage to
``enable facilities-based wireline internet access providers to
maximize their ability to deploy broadband internet access services and
facilities in competition with other platform providers, under a
regulatory framework that provides all market participants with the
flexibility to determine how best to structure their business
operations.'' Generally, ISPs that chose to elect common carrier status
were smaller carriers that served ``rural, sparsely-populated areas''
and obtained significant benefits from the provision of broadband
transmission services on a common carriage basis, including the ability
to participate in common tariff arrangements via the NECA pools and the
availability of high-cost universal service support.
157. We agree with NTCA and NECA that the broadband transmission
services currently offered by rural LECs under tariff differ
substantially from the broadband internet access services at issue in
this proceeding, and as such are not impacted by our decision to
reclassify broadband internet access service as an information service.
The term ``wireline broadband internet access service'' refers to ``a
mass-market retail service by wire that provides the capability to
transmit data to and receive data from all or substantially all
internet endpoints, including any capabilities that are incidental to
and enable the operation of the communications service, but excluding
dial-up internet access service.'' Broadband transmission services do
not provide end users with direct connectivity to the internet backbone
or content, but instead enable data traffic generated by end users to
be transported to an ISP's Access Service Connection Point over rural
LEC local exchange service facilities for subsequent interconnection
with the internet backbone.
158. Carriers offering broadband transmission service have never
been subject to the Title II Order forbearance framework. The Title II
Order forbearance framework with respect to broadband internet access
service did not encompass broadband transmission services and permitted
carriers to voluntarily elect to offer transmission services on a
common carriage basis pursuant to the Wireline Broadband Classification
Order. The Title II Order made clear that broadband transmission
services would continue to be subject to the full panoply of Title II
obligations (e.g., USF contributions), including those from which the
Commission forbore from in the Title II Order. Thus, only carriers that
elected to cease offering broadband transmission services and instead
offer broadband internet access services (including a transmission
service component) were subject to the Title II Order forbearance
framework (e.g., forbearance from USF contributions applied to such
carriers). Over one hundred providers opted-into the Title II Order
forbearance framework and in their letters to the Commission, they
noted that the transmission component would only be provided as part of
the complete broadband internet access service.
159. Today, we return to the pre-Title II Order status quo and
allow carriers to elect to offer broadband transmission services on a
common carrier basis, either pursuant to tariff or on a non-tariffed
basis. We find the reasoning in the Wireline Broadband Classification
Order for offering these options persuasive. Irrespective of the
regulatory classification of broadband internet access services, the
Commission has continuously permitted facilities-based wireline
carriers to provide broadband internet transmission services on a Title
II common carriage basis, with substantial flexibility in deciding how
such services may be offered (i.e., on a tariffed or non-tariffed
basis). Providing these options offers small carriers much-needed
regulatory certainty as they have sought to deploy and maintain
broadband internet access services to their customers. We reiterate
that broadband transmission services are not impacted by our decision
to reclassify broadband internet access service as an information
service.
160. We clarify that carriers that choose to offer transmission
service on a common carriage basis are, as under the Wireline Broadband
Classification
[[Page 7886]]
Order, subject to the full set of Title II obligations, to the extent
they applied before the Title II Order. Similarly, a wireless broadband
internet access provider may choose to offer the transmission component
as a telecommunications service and the transmission component of
wireless broadband internet access service as a telecommunications
service only if the entity that provides the transmission voluntarily
undertakes to provide it indifferently on a common carrier basis. Such
an offering is a common carrier service subject to Title II. In
addition, a wireless broadband internet access provider that chooses to
offer the telecommunications transmission component as a
telecommunications service may also be subject to the ``commercial
mobile service'' provisions of the Act. Further, we clarify that those
carriers that had previously been offering a broadband transmission
service (subject to the full panoply of Title II regulations) and that
elected to instead offer broadband internet access service after the
Title II Order now will be deemed to be offering an information
service. The Commission has never allowed carriers offering broadband
transmission services on a common carrier basis to opt in to the Title
II Order forbearance framework for those transmission services.
Carriers that prefer light-touch regulation may elect to offer
broadband internet access service as an information service. Although
WTA argues that allowing rural LECs to opt into the forbearance
framework will ``enable a much more level competitive playing field in
the retail marketplace,'' no other carriers are subject to that
framework, and we find that allowing carriers to opt into the
forbearance framework will result in a regulatory disparity. We
therefore reject WTA's argument that the Commission should continue to
permit opting into the Title II Order forbearance. To the extent that
other related issues are raised in the record, we find that those
issues are better addressed in the appropriate proceeding.
161. We also reject AT&T's assertion that the Commission should
conditionally forbear from all Title II regulations as a preventive
measure to address the contingency that a future Commission might seek
to reinstate the Title II Order. Although AT&T explains that
``conditional forbearance would provide an extra level of insurance
against the contingency that a future, politically motivated Commission
might try to reinstate a `common carrier' classification,'' we see no
need to address the complicated question of prophylactic forbearance
and find such extraordinary measures unnecessary.
3. Returning Broadband Privacy Authority to the FTC
162. By reinstating the information service classification of
broadband internet access service, we return jurisdiction to regulate
broadband privacy and data security to the Federal Trade Commission
(FTC), the nation's premier consumer protection agency and the agency
primarily responsible for these matters in the past. Restoring FTC
jurisdiction over ISPs will enable the FTC to apply its extensive
privacy and data security expertise to provide the uniform online
privacy protections that consumers expect and deserve.
163. Historically, the FTC protected the privacy of broadband
consumers, policing every online company's privacy practices
consistently and initiating numerous enforcement actions. In fact, the
FTC has ``brought over 500 enforcement actions protecting the privacy
and security of consumer information, including actions against ISPs
and against some of the biggest companies in the internet ecosystem.''
When the Commission reclassified broadband internet access service as a
common carriage telecommunications service in 2015, however, that
action stripped FTC authority over ISPs because the FTC is prohibited
from regulating common carriers. The effect of this decision was to
shift responsibility for regulating broadband privacy to the
Commission. And in lieu of an even playing field, the Commission
adopted sector-specific rules that deviated from the FTC's longstanding
framework. In March 2017, Congress voted under the Congressional Review
Act (CRA) to disapprove the Commission's 2016 Privacy Order, which
prevents us from adopting rules in substantially the same form.
164. Undoing Title II reclassification restores jurisdiction to the
agency with the most experience and expertise in privacy and data
security, better reflects congressional intent, and creates a level
playing field when it comes to internet privacy. Restoring FTC
authority to regulate broadband privacy and data security also fills
the consumer protection gap created by the Title II Order when it
stripped the FTC of jurisdiction over ISPs. Consumers expect
information to be ``treated consistently across the internet ecosystem
and that their personal information will be subject to the same
framework, in all contexts.'' Under the FTC's technology neutral
approach to privacy regulation, consumers will have the consistent
level of protection across the internet ecosystem that they expect.
With over 100 years of experience, only the FTC can apply consumer
protection rules consistently across industries. As NTCA contends, the
FTC has not only the legal jurisdiction, but also the subject matter
expertise. In 2007, the FTC issued a 167-page report that delved into
both the technical and legal bases of the internet and how the law
approaches it. Moreover, the FTC has been involved in numerous
initiatives that address consumer protection in the broadband
marketplace. The FTC's ``flexible, enforcement-focused approach has
enabled the agency to apply strong consumer privacy and security
protections across a wide range of changing technologies and business
models, without imposing unnecessary or undue burdens on industry.''
Moreover, the flexibility of the FTC's enforcement framework ``allows
room for new business models that could support expensive, next-
generation networks with revenue other than consumers' monthly bills.''
The FTC has already ``delivered the message to entities in a range of
fields--retailers, app developers, data brokers, health companies,
financial institutions, third-party service providers, and others--that
they need to provide consumers with strong privacy and data security
protections.'' The same approach should apply to ISPs. We also observe
that ISPs are not uniquely positioned with respect to their insight
into customers' private browsing behavior. As the FTC found in 2012,
``ISPs are just one type of large platform provider that may have
access to all or nearly all of a consumer's online activity. Like ISPs,
operating systems and browsers may be in a position to track all, or
virtually all, of a consumer's online activity to create highly
detailed profiles.'' And only the FTC operates on a national level
across industries, which is especially important when regulating
providers that operate across state lines. In light of the FTC's
decades of successful experience, including its oversight of ISP
privacy practices prior to 2015, we find arguments that we should
decline to reclassify to retain sector-specific control of ISP privacy
practices unpersuasive. The FTC has previously brought enforcement
actions against ISPs regarding internet access and related issues. The
FTC has also ``brought enforcement actions in matters involving access
to content via broadband and other internet access services,'' such as
the FTC's challenge to the proposed AOL and Time Warner merger, in
part, over concern for potential harm to consumers' broadband
[[Page 7887]]
internet access. We also note that while it may be true that the
Commission itself has longstanding privacy experience with respect to
traditional telephone service providers, we disagree that this history
uniquely qualifies the Commission to regulate the privacy practices of
ISPs or other online providers, when prior to 2015, the Commission did
not, and indeed lacked the authority to, regulate such providers. We do
not believe that experience with traditional telephone service
providers necessarily translates to experience or expertise with
respect to all communications providers. Some commenters object that
the FTC is not suited to protect privacy on the internet, citing the
FTC's narrower authority and fewer resources than the Commission and
the absence of specific statutory directive from Congress to the FTC to
regulate privacy. As discussed above, these criticisms are unfounded.
Furthermore, the uncertainty related to the Commission's current
authority over broadband privacy regulation created by the CRA
resolution of disapproval also weighs in favor of returning
jurisdiction to the FTC.
165. We also reject arguments that rely on the Ninth Circuit panel
decision holding that the common carrier exemption precludes FTC
oversight of non-common carriage activities of common carriers. As the
FCC's amicus letter explained in that case, the panel decision erred by
overlooking the textual relationship between the statutes governing the
FTC's and FCC's jurisdiction. We note that commenter concerns focus not
just on the FTC's privacy authority but its authority more generally.
We reject those arguments for the reasons stated above. Consistent with
the Commission's request, the Ninth Circuit granted rehearing en banc
of the panel decision, and in doing so it set aside the earlier panel
opinion. This en banc order means that the Title II Order's
reclassification of broadband internet access service serves as the
only current limit on the authority of the FTC to oversee the conduct
of internet service providers. We note that at any given time there
always may be some litigation pending somewhere in the country
challenging the scope or validity of various laws--whether the
Communications Act, FTC Act, or state consumer protection laws--that
the FCC might seek to rely on directly (in the case of the Act) or
indirectly (where relying in part on the availability of protections
provided by other laws). The Commission would be paralyzed if it had to
wait for all such litigation to be resolved before it acted. Because
the panel decision has been set aside in FTC v. AT&T Mobility, we do
not view that case as materially different than any other such pending
litigation--so we likewise do not view it as necessary to wait on the
resolution of that case before acting here. In light of these
considerations and the benefits of reclassification, we find objections
based on FTC v. AT&T Mobility insufficient to warrant a different
outcome.
4. Wireline Infrastructure
166. To the extent today's classification decision impacts the
deployment of wireline infrastructure, we will address that topic in
detail in proceedings specific to those issues. The importance of
facilitating broadband infrastructure deployment indicates that our
authority to address barriers to infrastructure deployment warrants
careful review in the appropriate proceedings. We disagree with
commenters who assert that Title II classification is necessary to
maintain our authority to promote infrastructure investment and
broadband deployment. Because the same networks are often used to
provide broadband and either telecommunications or cable service, we
will take further action as is necessary to promote broadband
deployment and infrastructure investment. Further, Title I
classification of broadband internet access services is consistent with
the Commission's broadband deployment objectives, whereas the Title II
regulatory environment undermines the very private investment and
buildout of broadband networks the Commission seeks to encourage.
Additionally, in the twenty states and the District of Columbia that
have reverse-preempted Commission jurisdiction over pole attachments,
those states rather than the Commission are empowered to regulate the
pole attachment process.
167. We are resolute that today's decision not be misinterpreted or
used as an excuse to create barriers to infrastructure investment and
broadband deployment. For example, we caution pole owners not to use
this Order as a pretext to increase pole attachment rates or to inhibit
broadband providers from attaching equipment--and we remind pole owners
of their continuing obligation to offer ``rates, terms, and conditions
[that] are just and reasonable.'' We will not hesitate to take action
where we identify barriers to broadband infrastructure deployment. We
have been working diligently to remove barriers to broadband deployment
and fully intend to continue to do so.
5. Wireless Infrastructure
168. When the Commission first classified wireless broadband
internet access as an information service in 2007, it emphasized that
certain statutory provisions in Section 224 (regarding pole
attachments) and 332(c)(7) (local authority over zoning) of the Act
would continue to apply where the same infrastructure was used to
provide a covered service (e.g., cable or telecommunications service)
as well as wireless broadband internet access. Section 224 gives cable
television systems and providers of telecommunications services the
right to attach to utility poles of power and telephone companies at
regulated rates. Section 332(c)(7) generally preserves state and local
authority over ``personal wireless service facilities'' siting or
modification, but subjects that authority to certain limitations. Among
other limitations, it provides that state or local government
regulation (1) ``shall not unreasonably discriminate among providers of
functionally equivalent services,'' (2) ``shall not prohibit or have
the effect of prohibiting the provision of personal wireless services''
and (3) may not regulate the siting of personal wireless service
facilities ``on the basis of the environmental effects of [RF]
emissions to the extent that such facilities comply with the
Commission's regulations concerning such emissions.''
169. As to Section 224, the Commission clarified in the Wireless
Broadband Internet Access Order that where the same infrastructure
would provide ``both telecommunications and wireless broadband internet
access service,'' the provisions of Section 224 governing pole
attachments would continue to apply to such infrastructure used to
provide both types of service. The Commission similarly clarified that
Section 332(c)(7)(B) would continue to apply to wireless broadband
internet access service where a wireless service provider uses the same
infrastructure to provide its ``personal wireless services'' and
wireless broadband internet access service.
170. We reaffirm the Commission's interpretations regarding the
application of Sections 224 and 332(c)(7) to wireless broadband
internet access service here. The Commission's rationale from 2007,
that commingling services does not change the fact that the facilities
are being used for the provisioning of services within the scope of the
statutory provision, remains equally valid today. This clarification
will alleviate concerns that wireless broadband internet access
providers not face increased barriers to infrastructure
[[Page 7888]]
deployment as a result of today's reclassification. This clarification
also is consistent with our commitment to promote broadband deployment
and close the digital divide.
171. Although the wireless infrastructure industry has changed
significantly since the adoption of the Wireless Broadband Internet
Access Order, it remains the case that cell towers and other forms of
network equipment can be used ``for the provision'' of both personal
wireless services and wireless broadband internet access on a
commingled basis. These communications facilities are sometimes built
by providers themselves, but are increasingly being deployed by third-
parties who then offer the use of these facilities to wireless service
providers for a variety of services, including telecommunications
services and information services. To remove any uncertainty, we
clarify that Section 332(c)(7) applies to facilities, including DAS or
small cells, deployed and offered by third-parties for the purpose of
provisioning communications services that include personal wireless
services. Consistent with the statutory provisions and Commission
precedent, we consider infrastructure that will be deployed for the
provision of personal wireless services, including third-party
facilities such as neutral-host deployments, to be ``facilities for the
provision of personal wireless services'' and therefore subject to
Section 332(c)(7) as ``personal wireless service facilities'' even
where such facilities also may be used for broadband internet access
services.
172. We reiterate our commitment to expand broadband access,
encourage innovation and close the digital divide. We will closely
monitor developments on broadband infrastructure deployment and move
quickly to address barriers in a future proceeding if necessary.
6. Universal Service
173. The reclassification of consumer and small business broadband
access as an information service does not affect or alter the
Commission's existing programs to support the deployment and
maintenance of broadband-capable networks, i.e., the Connect America
Fund's high-cost universal service support mechanisms. As explained in
the USF/ICC Transformation Order, the Commission has authority to
ensure that ``the national policy of promoting broadband deployment and
ubiquitous access to voice telephony services is fully realized'' and
require that ``carriers receiving support . . . offer broadband
capabilities to customers.'' What services a particular customer
subscribes to is irrelevant as long as high-cost support is used to
build and maintain a network that provides both voice and broadband
internet access service. Thus, the classification of broadband internet
access as an information service does not change the eligibility of
providers of those services to receive federal high-cost universal
service support.
174. Lifeline. We conclude that we need not address concerns in the
record about the effect of our reclassification of broadband internet
access service as an information service on the Lifeline program at
this time. In November 2017, we adopted an NPRM in the Lifeline
proceeding (Lifeline NPRM) (83 FR 2075) in which we proposed limiting
Lifeline support to facilities-based broadband service provided to a
qualifying low-income consumer over the eligible telecommunication
carrier's (ETC's) voice- and broadband-capable last-mile network, and
sought comment on discontinuing Lifeline support for service provided
over non-facilities-based networks, to advance our policy of focusing
Lifeline support to encourage investment in voice- and broadband-
capable networks. As explained in the Lifeline NPRM, we ``believe the
Commission has authority under Section 254(e) of the Act to provide
Lifeline support to ETCs that provide broadband service over
facilities-based broadband-capable networks that support voice
service'' and that ``[t]his legal authority does not depend on the
regulatory classification of broadband internet access service and,
thus, ensures the Lifeline program has a role in closing the digital
divide regardless of the regulatory classification of broadband
service.'' We thus find that today's reinstatement of the information
service classification for broadband internet access service does not
require us to address here our legal authority to continue supporting
broadband internet access service in the Lifeline program, as such
concerns are more appropriately addressed in the ongoing Lifeline
proceeding.
7. Preemption of Inconsistent State and Local Regulations
175. We conclude that regulation of broadband internet access
service should be governed principally by a uniform set of federal
regulations, rather than by a patchwork that includes separate state
and local requirements. Our order today establishes a calibrated
federal regulatory regime based on the pro-competitive, deregulatory
goals of the 1996 Act. Allowing state and local governments to adopt
their own separate requirements, which could impose far greater burdens
than the federal regulatory regime, could significantly disrupt the
balance we strike here. Federal courts have uniformly held that an
affirmative federal policy of deregulation is entitled to the same
preemptive effect as a federal policy of regulation. In addition,
allowing state or local regulation of broadband internet access service
could impair the provision of such service by requiring each ISP to
comply with a patchwork of separate and potentially conflicting
requirements across all of the different jurisdictions in which it
operates. Just as the Title II Order promised to ``exercise our
preemption authority to preclude states from imposing regulations on
broadband service that are inconsistent'' with the federal regulatory
scheme, we conclude that we should exercise our authority to preempt
any state or local requirements that are inconsistent with the federal
deregulatory approach we adopt today.
176. We therefore preempt any state or local measures that would
effectively impose rules or requirements that we have repealed or
decided to refrain from imposing in this order or that would impose
more stringent requirements for any aspect of broadband service that we
address in this order. This includes any state laws that would require
the disclosure of broadband internet access service performance
information, commercial terms, or network management practices in any
way inconsistent with the transparency rule we adopt herein. Our
transparency rule is carefully calibrated to reflect the information
that consumers, entrepreneurs, small businesses, and the Commission
needs to ensure a functioning market for broadband internet access
services and to ensure the Commission has sufficient information to
identify market-entry barriers--all without unduly burdening ISPs with
disclosure requirements that would raise the cost of service or
otherwise deter innovation within the network. Among other things, we
thereby preempt any so-called ``economic'' or ``public utility-type''
regulations, including common-carriage requirements akin to those found
in Title II of the Act and its implementing rules, as well as other
rules or requirements that we repeal or refrain from imposing today
because they could pose an obstacle to or place an undue burden on the
provision of broadband internet access service and conflict with the
deregulatory approach we adopt today. The terms ``economic regulation''
and ``public utility-type regulation,'' as used here, are terms of art
that the
[[Page 7889]]
Commission has used to include, among other things, requirements that
all rates and practices be just and reasonable; prohibitions on unjust
or unreasonable discrimination; tariffing requirements; accounting
requirements; entry and exit restrictions; interconnection obligations;
and unbundling or network-access requirements. We are not persuaded
that preemption is contrary to Section 706(a) of the 1996 Act, 47
U.S.C. 1302(a), insofar as that provision directs state commissions (as
well as this Commission) to promote the deployment of advanced
telecommunications capability. For one thing, as discussed infra, we
conclude that Section 706 does not constitute an affirmative grant of
regulatory authority, but instead simply provides guidance to this
Commission and the state commissions on how to use any authority
conferred by other provisions of federal and state law. For another,
nothing in this order forecloses state regulatory commissions from
promoting the goals set forth in Section 706(a) through measures that
we do not preempt here, such as by promoting access to rights-of-way
under state law, encouraging broadband investment and deployment
through state tax policy, and administering other generally applicable
state laws. Finally, insofar as we conclude that Section 706's goals of
encouraging broadband deployment and removing barriers to
infrastructure investment are best served by preempting state
regulation, we find that Section 706 supports (rather than prohibits)
the use of preemption here.
177. Although we preempt state and local laws that interfere with
the federal deregulatory policy restored in this order, we do not
disturb or displace the states' traditional role in generally policing
such matters as fraud, taxation, and general commercial dealings, so
long as the administration of such general state laws does not
interfere with federal regulatory objectives. We thus conclude that our
preemption determination is not contrary to Section 414 of the Act,
which states that ``[n]othing in [the Act] shall in any way abridge or
alter the remedies now existing at common law or by statute.'' Under
this order, states retain their traditional role in policing and
remedying violations of a wide variety of general state laws. The
record does not reveal how our preemption here would deprive states of
their ability to enforce any remedies that fall within the purview of
Section 414. In any case, a general savings clause like Section 414
``do[es] not preclude preemption where allowing state remedies would
lead to a conflict with or frustration of statutory purposes.'' Indeed,
the continued applicability of these general state laws is one of the
considerations that persuade us that ISP conduct regulation is
unnecessary here. Nor do we deprive the states of any functions
expressly reserved to them under the Act, such as responsibility for
designating eligible telecommunications carriers under Section 214(e);
exclusive jurisdiction over poles, ducts, conduits, and rights-of-way
when a state certifies that it has adopted effective rules and
regulations over those matters under Section 224(c); or authority to
adopt state universal service policies not inconsistent with the
Commission's rules under Section 254. We find no basis in the record to
conclude that our preemption determination would interfere with states'
authority to address rights-of-way safety issues. We note that we
continue to preempt any state from imposing any new state universal
service fund contributions on broadband internet access service. We
appreciate the many important functions served by our state and local
partners, and we fully expect that the states will ``continue to play
their vital role in protecting consumers from fraud, enforcing fair
business practices, for example, in advertising and billing, and
generally responding to consumer inquiries and complaints'' within the
framework of this order.
178. Legal Authority. We conclude that the Commission has legal
authority to preempt inconsistent state and local regulation of
broadband internet access service on several distinct grounds.
179. First, the U.S. Supreme Court and other courts have recognized
that, under what is known as the impossibility exception to state
jurisdiction, the FCC may preempt state law when (1) it is impossible
or impracticable to regulate the intrastate aspects of a service
without affecting interstate communications and (2) the Commission
determines that such regulation would interfere with federal regulatory
objectives. Here, both conditions are satisfied. Indeed, because state
and local regulation of the aspects of broadband internet access
service that we identify would interfere with the balanced federal
regulatory scheme we adopt today, they are plainly preempted.
180. As a preliminary matter, it is well-settled that internet
access is a jurisdictionally interstate service because ``a substantial
portion of internet traffic involves accessing interstate or foreign
websites.'' Thus, when the Commission first classified a form of
broadband internet access service in the Cable Modem Order, it
recognized that cable internet service is an ``interstate information
service.'' Five years later, the Commission reaffirmed the
jurisdictionally interstate nature of broadband internet access service
in the Wireless Broadband Internet Access Order. And even when the
Title II Order reclassified broadband internet access service as a
telecommunications service, the Commission continued to recognize that
``broadband internet access service is jurisdictionally interstate for
regulatory purposes.'' The record continues to show that broadband
internet access service is predominantly interstate because a
substantial amount of internet traffic begins and ends across state
lines.
181. Because both interstate and intrastate communications can
travel over the same internet connection (and indeed may do so in
response to a single query from a consumer), it is impossible or
impracticable for ISPs to distinguish between intrastate and interstate
communications over the internet or to apply different rules in each
circumstance. Accordingly, an ISP generally could not comply with state
or local rules for intrastate communications without applying the same
rules to interstate communications. We therefore reject the view that
the impossibility exception to state jurisdiction does not apply
because some aspects of broadband internet access service could
theoretically be regulated differently in different states. Even if it
were possible for New York to regulate aspects of broadband service
differently from New Jersey, for example, it would not be possible for
New York to regulate the use of a broadband internet connection for
intrastate communications without also affecting the use of that same
connection for interstate communications. The relevant question under
the impossibility exception is not whether it would be possible to have
separate rules in separate states, but instead whether it would be
feasible to allow separate state rules for intrastate communications
while maintaining uniform federal rules for interstate communications.
Thus, because any effort by states to regulate intrastate traffic would
interfere with the Commission's treatment of interstate traffic, the
first condition for conflict preemption is satisfied. OTI insists that
broadband service ``can easily be separated into interstate and
intrastate'' communications based on ``the location of the ISP.'' In
OTI's view, if ``the closest ISP headend, tower, or other facility to
the customer'' is in the same state as the customer, then the
customer's internet
[[Page 7890]]
communications are all intrastate. This view misapprehends the end-to-
end analysis employed by the Communications Act to distinguish
interstate and intrastate communications, which looks to where a
communication ultimately originates and terminates--such as the server
which hosts the content the consumer is requesting--rather than to
intermediate steps along the way (such as the location of the ISP).
Indeed, OTI's view that a communication is intrastate whenever the
``last mile'' facilities between the customer and the communications
carrier are within the same state would improperly deem virtually all
communications to be intrastate, including interstate telephone calls,
contrary to long-settled precedent.
182. The second condition for the impossibility exception to state
jurisdiction is also satisfied. For the reasons explained above, we
find that state and local regulation of the aspects of broadband
internet access service that we identify would interfere with the
balanced federal regulatory scheme we adopt today.
183. Second, the Commission has independent authority to displace
state and local regulations in accordance with the longstanding federal
policy of nonregulation for information services. For more than a
decade prior to the 1996 Act, the Commission consistently preempted
state regulation of information services (which were then known as
``enhanced services''). When Congress adopted the Commission's
regulatory framework and its deregulatory approach to information
services in the 1996 Act, it thus embraced our longstanding policy of
preempting state laws that interfere with our federal policy of
nonregulation.
184. Multiple provisions enacted by the 1996 Act confirm Congress's
approval of our preemptive federal policy of nonregulation for
information services. Section 230(b)(2) of the Act, as added by the
1996 Act, declares it to be ``the policy of the United States'' to
``preserve the vibrant and competitive free market that presently
exists for the internet and other interactive computer services''--
including ``any information service''--``unfettered by Federal or State
regulation.'' The Commission has observed that this provision makes
clear that ``federal authority [is] preeminent in the area of
information services'' and that information services ``should remain
free of regulation.'' To this same end, by directing that a
communications service provider ``shall be treated as a common carrier
under [this Act] only to the extent that it is engaged in providing
telecommunications services,'' Section 3(51)--also added by the 1996
Act--forbids any common-carriage regulation, whether federal or state,
of information services.
185. Finally, our preemption authority finds further support in the
Act's forbearance provision. Under Section 10(e) of the Act, Commission
forbearance determinations expressly preempt any contrary state
regulatory efforts. It would be incongruous if state and local
regulation were preempted when the Commission decides to forbear from a
provision that would otherwise apply, or if the Commission adopts a
regulation and then forbears from it, but not preempted when the
Commission determines that a requirement does not apply in the first
place. Nothing in the Act suggests that Congress intended for state or
local governments to be able to countermand a federal policy of
nonregulation or to possess any greater authority over broadband
internet access service than that exercised by the federal government.
Some commenters note that Section 253(c), 47 U.S.C. 253(c), preserves
certain state authority over telecommunications services. But that
provision has no relevance here, given our finding that broadband
internet access service is an information service. Although Section
253(c) recognizes that states have historically played a role in
regulating telecommunications services, there is no such tradition of
state regulation of information services, which have long been governed
by a federal policy of nonregulation.
8. Disability Access Provisions
186. The Communications Act provides the Commission with authority
to ensure that consumers with disabilities can access broadband
networks regardless of whether broadband internet access service is
classified as telecommunications service or information service. The
Twenty-First Century Communications and Video Accessibility Act of 2010
(CVAA) already applies a variety of accessibility requirements to
broadband internet access service. Congress adopted the CVAA after
recognizing that ``internet-based and digital technologies . . . driven
by growth in broadband . . . are now pervasive, offering innovative and
exciting ways to communicate and share information.'' Congress thus
clearly had internet-based communications technologies in mind when
enacting the accessibility provisions of Section 716 (as well as the
related provisions of Sections 717-718) and in providing important
protections with respect to advanced communications services (ACS). ACS
means: ``(A) interconnected VoIP service; (B) non-interconnected VoIP
service; (C) electronic messaging service; and (D) interoperable video
conferencing service.'' In particular, to ensure that people with
disabilities have access to the communications technologies of the
Twenty-First Century, the CVAA added several provisions to the
Communications Act, including Section 716 of the Act, which requires
that providers of advanced communications services (ACS) and
manufacturers of equipment used for ACS make their services and
products accessible to people with disabilities, unless it is not
achievable to do so. These mandates already apply according to their
terms in the context of broadband internet access service. The CVAA
also adopted a requirement, in Section 718, that ensures access to
internet browsers in wireless phones for people who are blind and
visually impaired. In addition, the CVAA directed the Commission to
enact regulations to prescribe, among other things, that networks used
to provide ACS ``may not impair or impede the accessibility of
information content when accessibility has been incorporated into that
content for transmission through . . . networks used to provide
[ACS].'' Finally, new Section 717 creates new enforcement and
recordkeeping requirements applicable to Sections 255, 716, and 718.
Section 710 of the Act addressing hearing aid compatibility and
implementing rules enacted thereunder also apply regardless of any
action taken in this Order. To the extent that other accessibility
issues arise, we will address those issues in separate proceedings in
furtherance of our statutory authority to ensure that broadband
networks are accessible to and usable by individuals with disabilities.
9. Continued Applicability of Title III Licensing Provisions
187. We also note that our decision today to classify wireless
broadband internet access service as an information service does not
affect the general applicability of the spectrum allocation and
licensing provisions of Title III and the Commission's rules to this
service. Title III generally provides the Commission with authority to
regulate ``radio communications'' and ``transmission of energy by
radio.'' Among other provisions, Title III gives the Commission the
authority to adopt rules preventing interference and allows it to
classify radio stations. It also establishes the basic licensing scheme
for radio stations, allowing the Commission to grant, revoke, or modify
[[Page 7891]]
licenses. Title III further allows the Commission to make such rules
and regulations and prescribe such restrictions and conditions as may
be necessary to carry out the provisions of the Act. Provisions
governing access to and use of spectrum (and their corresponding
Commission rules) do not depend on whether the service using the
spectrum is classified as a telecommunications or information service
under the Act.
II. A Light-Touch Framework To Restore Internet Freedom
188. For decades, the lodestar of the Commission's approach to
preserving internet freedom was a light-touch, market-based approach.
This approach debuted at the dawn of the commercial internet during the
Clinton Administration, when an overwhelming bipartisan consensus made
it national policy to preserve a digital free market ``unfettered by
Federal or State regulation.'' It continued during the Bush
Administration, as reflected in the ``Four Freedoms'' articulated by
Chairman Powell in 2004 and was then formally adopted by a unanimous
Commission in 2005 as well as in a series of classification decisions
reviewed above. These include the freedoms for consumers to (1)
``access the lawful internet content of their choice''; (2) ``run
applications and use services of their choice, subject to the needs of
law enforcement''; (3) ``connect their choice of legal devices that do
not harm the network''; and (4) ``enjoy competition among network
providers, application and service providers, and content providers.''
And it continued for the first six years of the Obama Administration.
We reaffirm and honor this longstanding, bipartisan commitment by
adopting a light-touch framework that will preserve internet freedom
for all Americans.
189. To implement that light-touch framework, we next reevaluate
the rules and enforcement regime adopted in the Title II Order. That
reevaluation is informed--as it must be--by the return of jurisdiction
to the Federal Trade Commission to police ISPs for anticompetitive acts
or unfair and deceptive practices. Against that backdrop, we first
decide to retain the transparency rule adopted in the Open Internet
Order with slight modifications. History has shown that transparency is
critical to openness--consumers and entrepreneurs are not afraid to
make their voices heard when ISPs engage in practices to which they
object. And we conclude that preexisting federal protections--alongside
the transparency rule we adopt today--are not only sufficient to
protect internet freedom, but will do so more effectively and at lower
social cost than the Title II Order's conduct rules. In short, we
believe the light-touch framework we adopt today will pave the way for
additional innovation and investment that will facilitate greater
consumer access to more content, services, and devices, and greater
competition.
A. Transparency
190. ``Sunlight,'' Justice Brandeis famously noted, ``is . . . the
best of disinfectants.'' This is the case in our domain. Properly
tailored transparency disclosures provide valuable information to the
Commission to enable it to meet its statutory obligation to observe the
communications marketplace to monitor the introduction of new services
and technologies, and to identify and eliminate potential marketplace
barriers for the provision of information services. Such disclosures
also provide valuable information to other internet ecosystem
participants; transparency substantially reduces the possibility that
ISPs will engage in harmful practices, and it incentivizes quick
corrective measures by providers if problematic conduct is identified.
Appropriate disclosures help consumers make informed choices about
their purchase and use of broadband internet access services. Moreover,
clear disclosures improve consumer confidence in ISPs' practices while
providing entrepreneurs and other small businesses the information they
may need to innovate and improve products.
191. Today, we commit to balanced ISP transparency requirements
based on a sound legal footing. We return, with minor adjustments, to
the transparency rule adopted in the 2010 Open Internet Order, which
provides consumers and the Commission with essential information while
minimizing the burdens imposed on ISPs. In so doing, we modify the
existing transparency rule to eliminate many of the burdensome
additional reporting obligations adopted by the Commission in the Title
II Order. We find that those additional obligations do not benefit
consumers, entrepreneurs, or the Commission sufficiently to outweigh
the burdens imposed on ISPs. The transparency rule we adopt will aid
the Commission in ``identifying . . . market entry barriers for
entrepreneurs and other small businesses in the provision and ownership
of . . . information services.'' We also conclude that our transparency
rule readily survives First Amendment scrutiny. The disclosure
requirements we adopt apply to both fixed and mobile ISPs.
1. History of the Transparency Rule
192. The Open Internet Order. The transparency rule, first adopted
in the Open Internet Order, requires both fixed and mobile ISPs to
``publicly disclose accurate information regarding the network
management practices, performance, and commercial terms of its
broadband internet access services sufficient for consumers to make
informed choices.'' In addition, the Open Internet Order provided
guidance on both what information should be disclosed and how those
disclosures should be made. The Commission described the types of
information that should be included in each category, but emphasized
the importance of flexibility in implementing the rule, making clear
that ``effective disclosures will likely include some or all'' of the
listed types of information. Though the other rules adopted in the Open
Internet Order were overturned, the D.C. Circuit upheld the
transparency rule in Verizon.
193. 2011 Advisory Guidance. On June 30, 2011, the Enforcement
Bureau and Office of General Counsel released guidance ``regarding
specific methods of disclosure that will be considered to comply with
the transparency rule,'' addressing concerns about the scope of
required disclosures and potential burdens on small providers. The 2011
Advisory Guidance provided detail on methods for disclosure of actual
performance metrics, and the contents of the disclosures regarding
network practices, performance characteristics, and commercial terms,
and clarified the requirement that disclosures be made ``at the point
of sale.'' The 2011 Advisory Guidance clarified that disclosure of the
information listed in paragraphs 56 and 98 of the Open Internet Order
was sufficient to satisfy the transparency rule notwithstanding the
Open Internet Order's assertion that the list was ``not necessarily
exhaustive, nor is it a safe harbor.'' Paragraph 56 of the Open
Internet Order provided the following non-exhaustive list of
disclosures: network practices, including congestion management,
application-specific behavior, device attachment rules, and security;
performance characteristics, including a service description and the
impact of specialized services; and commercial terms, including
pricing, privacy policies, and redress options. Paragraph 98 made clear
that mobile ISPs must comply with the transparency requirements and
states that such providers must ``disclose their third-party device and
application certification procedures, if any'';
[[Page 7892]]
``clearly explain their criteria for any restrictions on use of their
network''; and ``expeditiously inform device and application providers
of any decisions to deny access to the network or of a failure to
approve their particular devices or applications.''
194. 2014 Advisory Guidance. In July 2014, in the wake of the
Verizon decision, the Enforcement Bureau issued further guidance
emphasizing the importance of consistency between an ISP's disclosures
under the transparency rule and that provider's advertising claims or
other public statements. The 2014 Advisory Guidance explained that the
transparency rule ``prevents a broadband internet access provider from
making assertions about its service that contain errors, are
inconsistent with the provider's disclosure statement, or are
misleading or deceptive.''
195. Title II Order. In the Title II Order, the Commission
broadened the transparency rule's requirements by interpreting the rule
to mandate certain additional reporting obligations it termed
``enhancements.'' These additional reporting obligations, although
falling within the same broad categories as those listed in the Open
Internet Order, required that providers include far greater technical
detail in their disclosures. For example, all ISPs, except small
providers exempt under the Small Provider Waiver Order, were required
to make specific disclosures regarding the commercial terms (including
specific information regarding prices and fees), performance
characteristics (including, for example, packet loss and a requirement
that these disclosures be reasonably related to the performance a
consumer could expect in the geographic area in which they are
purchasing service), and network practices (including, for example,
application and user-based practices) of the broadband internet access
services they offer. The Open Internet Order, read together with the
2011 Advisory Guidance, limited the performance characteristic
disclosures to a service description (``[a] general description of the
service, including the service technology, expected and actual access
speed and latency, and the suitability of the service for real-time
applications'') and the impact of specialized services. The Open
Internet Order included specific disclosures related to congestion
management, application-specific behavior, device attachment rules, and
security. The Title II Order also established a safe harbor for the
form and format of disclosures intended for consumers and delegated
development of the format to the agency's Consumer Advisory Committee
(CAC). The 2016 Advisory Guidance, released on delegated authority,
provided examples of acceptable methodologies for disclosure of
performance characteristics and offered guidance regarding compliance
with the point of sale requirement. For example, the guidance notes
that for many fixed providers, performance is likely to be consistent
across the provider's footprint so long as the same technology is
deployed and that in such a case a single disclosure for the full
service area may be sufficient. By contrast, mobile performance may
vary, and the guidance suggested the use of CMA as an appropriate
geographic area on which to base disclosures.
2. Refining the Transparency Rule
196. Today, we retain the transparency rule as established in the
Open Internet Order, with some modifications, and eliminate the
additional reporting obligations of the Title II Order. We find many of
those additional reporting obligations significantly increased the
burdens imposed on ISPs without providing countervailing benefits to
consumers or the Commission. As a result, we recalibrate the
requirements under the transparency rule. Specifically, we adopt the
following rule:
Any person providing broadband internet access service shall
publicly disclose accurate information regarding the network management
practices, performance, and commercial terms of its broadband internet
access services sufficient to enable consumers to make informed choices
regarding the purchase and use of such services and entrepreneurs and
other small businesses to develop, market, and maintain internet
offerings. Such disclosure shall be made via a publicly available,
easily accessible website or through transmittal to the Commission.
For purposes of these rules, ``consumer'' includes any subscriber
to the ISP's broadband internet access service, and ``person'' includes
any ``individual, group of individuals, corporation, partnership,
association, unit of government or legal entity, however organized.''
197. In doing so, we note that the record overwhelmingly supports
retaining at least some transparency requirements. Crucially, the
transparency rule will ensure that consumers have the information
necessary to make informed choices about the purchase and use of
broadband internet access service, which promotes a competitive
marketplace for those services. Disclosure supports innovation,
investment, and competition by ensuring that entrepreneurs and other
small businesses have the technical information necessary to create and
maintain online content, applications, services, and devices, and to
assess the risks and benefits of embarking on new projects. We reject
commenter assertions that we should not maintain any transparency
requirements. CenturyLink does not identify which requirements from the
2010 transparency rule it believes could arguably be ``onerous.''
Further, as discussed above, we find that a transparency requirement is
necessary and sufficient to protect internet openness, given that we
lack authority to adopt conduct rules and in addition find that an
enforceable transparency rule obviates the need for bright line conduct
rules.
198. What is more, disclosure increases the likelihood that ISPs
will abide by open internet principles by reducing the incentives and
ability to violate those principles, that the internet community will
identify problematic conduct, and that those affected by such conduct
will be in a position to make informed competitive choices or seek
available remedies for anticompetitive, unfair, or deceptive practices.
Transparency thereby ``increases the likelihood that harmful practices
will not occur in the first place and that, if they do, they will be
quickly remedied.'' We apply our transparency rule to broadband
internet access service, as well as functional equivalents or any
service that is used to evade the transparency requirements we adopt
today. As the Commission explained in the Open Internet Order, ``a key
factor in determining whether a service is used to evade the scope of
the rules is whether the service is used as a substitute for broadband
internet access service. For example, an internet access service that
provides access to a substantial subset of internet endpoints based on
end users' preference to avoid certain content, applications, or
services; internet access services that allow some uses of the internet
(such as access to the World Wide Web) but not others (such as email);
or a `Best of the Web' internet access service that provides access to
100 top websites could not be used to evade the open internet rules
applicable to `broadband internet access service.' '' We caution ISPs
that they may not evade application of the transparency rule ``simply
by blocking end users' access to some internet points.''
[[Page 7893]]
a. Content of Required Disclosures
199. We require ISPs to prominently disclose network management
practices, performance, and commercial terms of their broadband
internet access service, and find substantial record support (including
from ISPs) for following the course set out by the Open Internet Order.
We find that the elements of the transparency rule we adopt today help
consumers make the most educated decision as to which ISP to choose and
keep entrepreneurs and other small businesses effectively informed of
ISP practices so that they can develop, market, and maintain internet
offerings. Although we agree with the Open Internet Order that ``the
best approach is to allow flexibility in implementation of the
transparency rule,'' we describe the specific requirements to guide
ISPs and ensure that consumers, entrepreneurs, and other small
businesses receive sufficient information to make our rule effective.
200. Network Management Practices. In the Open Internet Order, the
Commission required ISPs to disclose their congestion management,
application-specific behavior, device attachment rules, and security
practices. We adopt those same requirements and further require ISPs to
disclose any blocking, throttling, affiliated prioritization, or paid
prioritization in which they engage. Although requiring disclosure of
network management practices imposes some burden on ISPs, we find the
benefits of enabling the public and the Commission to identify any
problematic conduct and suggest fixes substantially outweigh those
costs. The record generally supports disclosure of ISP network
practices.
201. We specifically require all ISPs to disclose:
Blocking. Any practice (other than reasonable network
management elsewhere disclosed) that blocks or otherwise prevents end
user access to lawful content, applications, service, or non-harmful
devices, including a description of what is blocked.
Throttling. Any practice (other than reasonable network
management elsewhere disclosed) that degrades or impairs access to
lawful internet traffic on the basis of content, application, service,
user, or use of a non-harmful device, including a description of what
is throttled.
Affiliated Prioritization. Any practice that directly or
indirectly favors some traffic over other traffic, including through
use of techniques such as traffic shaping, prioritization, or resource
reservation, to benefit an affiliate, including identification of the
affiliate.
Paid Prioritization. Any practice that directly or
indirectly favors some traffic over other traffic, including through
use of techniques such as traffic shaping, prioritization, or resource
reservation, in exchange for consideration, monetary or otherwise.
Congestion Management. Descriptions of congestion
management practices, if any. These descriptions should include the
types of traffic subject to the practices; the purposes served by the
practices; the practices' effects on end users' experience; criteria
used in practices, such as indicators of congestion that trigger a
practice, including any usage limits triggering the practice, and the
typical frequency of congestion; usage limits and the consequences of
exceeding them; and references to engineering standards, where
appropriate.
Application-Specific Behavior. Whether and why the ISP
blocks or rate-controls specific protocols or protocol ports, modifies
protocol fields in ways not prescribed by the protocol standard, or
otherwise inhibits or favors certain applications or classes of
applications.
Device Attachment Rules. Any restrictions on the types of
devices and any approval procedures for devices to connect to the
network.
Security. Any practices used to ensure end-user security
or security of the network, including types of triggering conditions
that cause a mechanism to be invoked (but excluding information that
could reasonably be used to circumvent network security). We expect
ISPs to exercise their judgment in deciding whether it is necessary and
appropriate to disclose particular security measures. The Commission's
primary concern is those security measures likely to affect a
consumer's ability to access the content, applications, services, and
devices of his or her choice. As a result, we do not expect ISPs to
disclose internal network security measures that do not directly bear
on a consumer's choices.
We do not mandate disclosure of any other network management
practices. Notably, we define ``reasonable network management'' to mean
a practice ``appropriate and tailored to achieving a legitimate network
management purpose, taking into account the particular network
architecture and technology of the broadband internet access service.''
The record reflects an overwhelming preference for this approach from
the Open Internet Order, which provides ISPs greater flexibility and
certainty.
202. Performance Characteristics. In the Open Internet Order, the
Commission required ISPs to disclose a service description as well as
the impact of specialized services (non-broadband internet access
service data services) on performance. We find that the Open Internet
Order's performance metric disclosures benefit consumers without
placing an undue burden on ISPs.
203. We specifically require all ISPs to disclose:
Service Description. A general description of the service,
including the service technology, expected and actual access speed and
latency, and the suitability of the service for real-time applications.
For purposes of satisfying this requirement, fixed ISPs that choose to
participate in the Measuring Broadband America (MBA) program may
disclose their results as a sufficient representation of the actual
performance their customers can expect to experience. Fixed ISPs that
do not participate may use the methodology from the MBA program to
measure actual performance, or may disclose actual performance based on
internal testing, consumer speed test data, or other data regarding
network performance, including reliable, relevant data from third-party
sources. Mobile ISPs that have access to reliable information on
network performance may disclose the results of their own or third-
party testing. Those mobile ISPs that do not have reasonable access to
such network performance data may disclose a Typical Speed Range (TSR)
representing the range of speeds and latency that can be expected by
most of their customers, for each technology/service tier offered,
along with a statement that such information is the best approximation
available to the broadband provider of the actual speeds and latency
experienced by its subscribers.
Impact of Non-Broadband Internet Access Service Data
Services. If applicable, what non-broadband internet access service
data services, if any, are offered to end users, and whether and how
any non-broadband internet access service data services may affect the
last-mile capacity available for, and the performance of, broadband
internet access service.
204. Commercial Terms. In the Open Internet Order, the Commission
required ISPs to disclose commercial terms of service, including price,
privacy policies, and redress options. The record in this proceeding
supports retaining these disclosures. These disclosures inform the
Commission, consumers, entrepreneurs, and other small businesses about
the parameters of the service, without imposing costly
[[Page 7894]]
burdens on ISPs. We therefore require ISPs to make the following
disclosures:
Price. For example, monthly prices, usage-based fees, and
fees for early termination or additional network services.
Privacy Policies. A complete and accurate disclosure about
the ISP's privacy practices, if any. For example, whether any network
management practices entail inspection of network traffic, and whether
traffic is stored, provided to third parties, or used by the ISP for
non-network management purposes.
Redress Options. Practices for resolving complaints and
questions from consumers, entrepreneurs, and other small businesses.
205. Eliminating the Title II Order's Additional Reporting
Obligations. Today, we return to a more balanced approach--one that
provides sufficient information for the Commission to meet its
statutory requirements, enables consumers to make informed choices
about the purchase and use of broadband internet access service, and
ensures entrepreneurs and other small businesses can develop, market,
and maintain internet offerings, while minimizing costly and
unnecessary burdens on ISPs.
206. We eliminate the additional reporting obligations adopted in
the Title II Order and the related guidance in the 2016 Advisory
Guidance and return to the requirements established in the Open
Internet Order. We find that these additional reporting obligations
unduly burden ISPs without providing a comparable benefit to consumers.
That is especially true for the performance metric, which mandated
disclosure of packet loss, geographically-specific disclosures, and
disclosure of performance at peak usage times among other things.
207. The record supports the elimination of these additional
reporting obligations and our return to the requirements under the Open
Internet Order. The record indicates that the additional performance
disclosures are among the most burdensome. CenturyLink estimated that
during the two-year period from February 2015 through February 2017,
1,650 hours of employee time were required to comply with the
additional reporting obligations, compared to 860 additional hours
spent complying with the other new requirements of the Title II Order.
Disclosure of packet loss, for example, requires providers to conduct
additional engineering analysis. Notably, the Office of Management and
Budget (OMB) in the prior Administration declined to approve packet
loss when reviewing these additional reporting obligations for mobile
ISPs, suggesting concern that the additional reporting obligations
provided little consumer benefit relative to their cost. After all,
consumers have little understanding of what packet loss means; what
they do want to know is whether their internet access service will
support real-time applications, which is the consumer-facing impact of
these performance metrics. Although some commenters argue that
additional reporting of these esoteric metrics are valuable to some
consumers and entrepreneurs, they provide inadequate support for these
benefits. In addition, providing such information imposes significant
costs on providers. Weighing the additional costs to ISPs against the
limited incremental benefits to consumers, entrepreneurs, and small
businesses, we conclude that the net benefits of these additional
reporting obligations are likely negative. The approach we take today
achieves the benefits of transparency at much lower cost than the Title
II Order.
208. Small Providers. Small providers have asked us to maintain the
exemption found in the Small Provider Order to the extent that any of
additional reporting obligations still apply. Because the requirements
we adopt today eliminate all of these additional obligations and do not
impose disparately high burdens on small providers, we find an
exemption for small providers unnecessary. Further, the requirements
are critical to ensuring that consumers have sufficient information to
make informed choices in their selection of ISPs and to deter ISPs from
secretly erecting barriers to market entry by entrepreneurs and other
small businesses. As a result, we decline to provide an exemption for
smaller providers at this time.
b. Means and Format of Disclosure
209. Means of Disclosure. The Commission relies on ISP disclosures
to identify market-entry barriers for entrepreneurs and small
businesses and ensure consumers have the information they need in
selecting an ISP. And given the sheer number of ISPs offering service
throughout the country--4,559 at last count--we believe the most
effective way to monitor for any such barriers is to require the public
disclosure of an ISP's practices so that Commission staff can review
them while letting consumers, entrepreneurs, and other small businesses
report to the Commission any market-barriers they discover.
Accordingly, ISPs must publicly disclose the information required by
our transparency rule.
210. We give ISPs two options for disclosure. First, they may
include the disclosures on a publicly available, easily accessible
website. Consistent with Commission precedent, we expect that ISPs will
make disclosures in a manner accessible by people with disabilities.
ISPs doing so need not distribute hard copy versions of the required
disclosures and need not file them with the Commission, which can
review the disclosures as needed on the ISPs' websites. For ISPs
electing this option, we reaffirm the means of disclosure requirement
from the Open Internet Order and the clarification found in the 2011
Advisory Guidance. Alternatively, ISPs may transmit their disclosures
to the Commission, and we will make them available on a publicly
available, easily accessible website. We direct the Consumer and
Governmental Affairs Bureau, in coordination with the Wireline
Competition Bureau, to issue a Public Notice explaining how ISPs can
exercise this option. We also note that ISPs that do not transmit their
disclosures to the FCC will be deemed as having elected the first
option (and may later elect that option despite prior transmittal by
informing the Commission in a manner specified in the aforementioned
Public Notice). By offering these two options, we allow ISPs (and
especially smaller ISPs) the ability to choose the least burdensome
method of disclosure that will nonetheless ensure that Commission
staff, consumers, entrepreneurs, and other small businesses have access
to the information they need in carrying out our obligation to identify
market-entry barriers.
211. We also eliminate the direct notification requirement adopted
in the Title II Order. We find the direct notification requirement
unduly burdensome to ISPs and unnecessary in light of the other forms
of public disclosure required. In contrast, we find that the
disclosures adopted in the Open Internet Order and 2011 Advisory
Guidance appropriately balance making information easy to reach and the
costs of disclosure for ISPs.
212. Format of Disclosure. We eliminate the consumer broadband
label safe harbor for form and format of disclosures adopted in the
Title II Order. Adopting the label could require some ISPs to expend
substantial resources to tailor their disclosures to fit the format.
And limited adoption, caused by the potentially high burdens associated
with adapting disclosures to a particular format, significantly reduces
the value of the uniform format. Moreover, mandating such a format
would increase the burden for those ISPs required to
[[Page 7895]]
revise their existing disclosure to conform to the mandated format. We
find that requiring all ISPs to disclose the same information,
regardless of format, will allow for comparability between offerings,
and enable the Commission to meet its statutory reporting requirements.
3. Authority for the Transparency Rule
213. Just as the Commission did in the Open Internet Order, we rely
on Section 257 of the Communications Act as authority for the
transparency requirements we retain. Section 257(a) directs the
Commission to ``identify[ ] and eliminat[e] . . . market entry barriers
for entrepreneurs and other small businesses in the provision and
ownership of telecommunications services and information services, or
in the provision of parts or services to providers of
telecommunications services and information services.'' Section 257(a)
set a deadline of 15 months from the enactment of the 1996 Act for the
Commission's initial effort in that regard, and Section 257(c) directs
the Commission, triennially thereafter, to report to Congress on such
marketplace barriers and how they have been addressed by regulation or
could be addressed by recommended statutory changes. Consistent with
the Commission's longstanding view, Section 257(c) is properly
understood as imposing a continuing obligation on the agency to
identify barriers described in Section 257(a) that may emerge in the
future, rather than limited to those identified in the original Section
257(a) proceeding. Because Sections 257(a) and (c) clearly anticipate
that the Commission and Congress would take steps to help eliminate
previously-identified marketplace barriers, limiting the triennial
reports only to those barriers identified in the original Section
257(a) proceeding could make such reports of little to no ongoing value
over time. We thus find it far more reasonable to interpret Section
257(c) as contemplating that the Commission will perform an ongoing
market review to identify any new barriers to entry, and that the
statutory duty to ``identify and eliminate'' implicitly empowers the
Commission to require disclosures from those third parties who possess
the information necessary for the Commission and Congress to find and
remedy market entry barriers. Although Section 257 does not specify
precisely how the Commission should obtain and analyze information for
purposes of its reports to Congress, we construe the statutory mandate
to ``identify'' the presence of market barriers as including within it
direct authority to collect evidence to prove that such barriers exist.
While this direct authority suffices to support the Commission's
adoption of the transparency rule, Sections 4, 201(b), and 303(r) of
the Act also give us rulemaking authority to implement the Act,
including the provisions we rely on as authority for our transparency
requirements. In his partial concurrence and partial dissent in
Verizon, Judge Silberman stated with respect to the transparency rule
that ``[t]he Commission is required to make triennial reports to
Congress on `market entry barriers' in information service, and
requiring disclosure of network management practices appears to be
reasonably ancillary to that duty.''
214. Our disclosure requirements will help us both identify and
address potential market entry barriers in the provision and ownership
of information services and the provision of parts and services to
information service providers. In particular, some internet
applications and services previously have been found to be information
services, and, more generally, entrepreneurs and small businesses
participating in the internet marketplace could be seeking to act as
either providers of information services or providers of parts and
services to information services (or both). The language of Section
257(a) appears reasonably read to encompass those entrepreneurs' and
small businesses' services under one or more of the covered categories,
and there is no dispute in the record in that regard. Because we find
that internet entrepreneurs and small businesses that depend on their
customers using broadband internet access service are covered by
Section 257(a) in any case, we need not and do not address with greater
specificity the specific category or categories into which particular
edge services fall. In addition, the manner in which an ISP provides
broadband internet access service, including but not limited to its
network management practices, can affect how well particular internet
applications or services of entrepreneurs and small businesses perform
when used by that ISP's subscribers. Aspects of the performance of
broadband internet access services, particularly if undisclosed, thus
could constitute barriers within the scope of Section 257(a) in the
future, depending on how the marketplace evolves, regardless of whether
or not particular practices do so today. For example, if ISPs do not
disclose key details of how they provide broadband internet access
service, that could leave entrepreneurs and small businesses
participating in the internet marketplace unable to determine how well
particular existing or contemplated offerings are likely to perform for
users, and thus unable to determine if their service will be usable to
a sufficient number of potential customers to make the offering viable.
Such undisclosed practices also can leave consumers unable to judge
which broadband internet access service offerings will best meet their
needs given the applications and service they wish to use. As a result,
even if a sufficient number of consumers theoretically are accessible
by a broadband internet access service offering with sufficient
technical characteristics to make a given internet application or
service viable, an entrepreneur's or small business's entry into the
market for that service could be undermined if consumers are unable to
identify which of the various broadband internet access services
offerings has the required technical characteristics. By contrast, the
record reveals that the disclosure of practices and service
characteristics we require today helps entrepreneurs and small
businesses understand how well particular internet application or
service offerings are likely to work with particular ISPs' broadband
internet access services and helps consumers make the most educated
choice among ISPs and particular broadband internet access service
offerings, especially if they have particular interests in using
internet applications or services that are highly dependent on
broadband internet access service performance. The disclosures
themselves thus are likely to reduce any potential risk of particular
practices being such a barrier--had they not been publicly disclosed--
and also enable us to recommend to Congress any legislative changes
that we might find warranted based on our analysis of these practices.
While we observe that the transparency rule will help eliminate
potential barriers, our reliance on Section 257 as authority for the
transparency rule centers on the need for that rule to identify
barriers and report to Congress in that regard. Contrary to some
arguments, we thus do not interpret Section 257 as an over-arching
grant of authority to eliminate any and all barriers we might identify.
We also are not persuaded by summary claims that Section 257 does not
grant us authority here insofar as those claims lack meaningful
analysis of the text of that provision. Thus, we continue to believe
that Section 257 provides us authority for the rule we adopt.
215. We believe that eliminating market entry barriers in the
provision
[[Page 7896]]
and ownership of information services and the provision of parts and
services to information service providers will help bring the benefits
of new inventions and developments to the public. In addition, we
conclude that the oversight over ISPs' practices that the Commission,
FTC, and other antitrust and consumer protection authorities can
exercise as a result of the transparency rule likewise will promote
innovation and competition, spreading the benefits of technological
development to the American people broadly.
216. The Transparency Requirements Are Consistent With the First
Amendment. We conclude that the transparency requirements represent
permissible regulation of commercial speech. The ultimate effect of the
required disclosures is to ensure that key details regarding service
characteristics, rates, and terms of broadband internet access service
offerings are available to potential customers before they make their
purchasing decisions. As stated above, ISPs have two options for
complying with the transparency requirements. One is to make the
disclosures on a publicly available, easily accessible website.
Alternatively, ISPs can elect to simply provide that information to the
Commission, which will then itself make the information publicly
available. The Title II Order evaluated the transparency rule at issue
there under Zauderer v. Office of Disciplinary Counsel of Supreme Court
of Ohio, and there is some record support for applying that framework.
We recognize that there remains some debate regarding the application
of Zauderer, as opposed to the Central Hudson framework that generally
governs First Amendment review of commercial speech regulation. We need
not resolve that here, because we find that our rule would withstand
scrutiny even under Central Hudson. In particular, our transparency
rule directly advances substantial government interests and is no more
extensive than necessary.
217. The transparency requirements we retain directly advance
substantial government interests in encouraging competition and
innovation. The Act itself reveals the significance of these interests.
In Section 257 of the Act, Congress specifically directed the
Commission to identify market entry barriers in the provision of
information services and their inputs, eliminating them where possible,
and reporting to Congress on the need for any statutory changes
required to address such barriers. In carrying out our responsibilities
under Section 257, Congress directed us to advance, among other things,
``vigorous economic competition'' and ``technological advancement.''
Such interests are similar to those recognized as substantial by
courts, as well.
218. The disclosure of information regarding broadband internet
access service characteristics, rates, and terms directly advance those
statutory directives. We thus disagree with arguments that there is
insufficient justification for our transparency requirements to
withstand First Amendment scrutiny. Moreover, commenters do not cite
precedent demonstrating that only ``systematic or enduring problem[s]''
can provide the basis for requirements that withstand First Amendment
scrutiny. Broadband internet access service subscribers will be able to
use the disclosed information to evaluate broadband internet access
service offerings and determine which offering will best enable the use
of the applications and service they desire. This helps guard against
the potential barrier to entry and deterrent to technological
advancement that otherwise could be faced by entrepreneurs' and small
business' innovative internet applications and service offerings, which
may be dependent on the technical characteristics of broadband internet
access service. The information disclosed by ISPs also is relevant to
internet application and service providers' purchase of services from
those ISPs. The record reveals evidence that a number of the internet
applications and services that might be particularly sensitive to the
manner in which an ISP provides broadband internet access service
potentially could benefit from the freedom this order provides for
providers of such services and ISPs to enter prioritization
arrangements to better ensure the performance of those internet
applications and services. Thus, the disclosures enable entrepreneurs,
small businesses, and other participants in the internet marketplace to
evaluate how well their offerings will perform by default relative to
the prioritization services that ISPs offer them. Enabling internet
application and service providers to evaluate their options in this way
helps reduce barriers to entry that otherwise could exist and
encourages entrepreneurs' and small businesses' ability to compete and
develop and advance innovating offerings in furtherance of our
statutory objectives. In addition to those considerations, as the
Commission has recognized, disclosures help ensure accountability by
ISPs and the potential for quick remedies if problematic practices
occur. The disclosures also provide the Commission the information it
needs for the evaluation required by Section 257 of the Act, enabling
us to spur regulatory action or seek legislative changes as needed. The
transparency rule we retain thus directly advances the substantial
government interests identified in Section 257 of the Act.
219. The transparency requirements also are no more extensive than
necessary. The disclosures covered by our transparency rule are tied to
our duties under Section 257 of the Communications Act. We also observe
in this regard that the most significant concerns were raised with
respect to the additional reporting obligations adopted in the Title II
Order and here we eliminate those requirements in favor of a rule
consistent in scope with the 2010 transparency rule. In addition, an
ISP's direct public disclosure of the information encompassed by the
transparency rule is just one option; it may instead submit the
information to the Commission, which would then make public. We thus
conclude that the transparency requirements are appropriately tailored
to the Congressionally-recognized goals that we seek to advance.
B. Bright-Line and General Conduct Rules
220. We eliminate the conduct rules adopted in the Title II Order--
including the general conduct rule and the prohibitions on paid
prioritization, blocking, and throttling. We do so for three reasons.
First, the transparency rule we adopt, in combination with the state of
broadband internet access service competition and the antitrust and
consumer protection laws, obviates the need for conduct rules by
achieving comparable benefits at lower cost. Second, scrutinizing
closely each prior conduct rule, we find that the costs of each rule
outweigh its benefits. Third, the record does not identify any legal
authority to adopt conduct rules for all ISPs, and we decline to
distort the market with a patchwork of non-uniform, limited-purpose
rules.
1. Transparency Leads to Openness
221. Transparency, competition, antitrust laws, and consumer
protection laws achieve similar benefits as conduct rules at lower
cost. The effect of the transparency rule we adopt is that ISP
practices that involve blocking, throttling, and other behavior that
may give rise to openness concerns will be disclosed to the Commission
and the
[[Page 7897]]
public. As the Commission found in the Open Internet Order,
``disclosure increases the likelihood that broadband providers will
abide by open internet principles, and that the internet community will
identify problematic conduct and suggest fixes . . . thereby
increas[ing] the chances that harmful practices will not occur in the
first place and that, if they do, they will be quickly remedied.'' The
transparency rule will also assist ``third-party experts such as
independent engineers and consumer watchdogs to monitor and evaluate
network management practices.''
222. History demonstrates that public attention, not heavy-handed
Commission regulation, has been most effective in deterring ISP threats
to openness and bringing about resolution of the rare incidents that
arise. The Commission has had transparency requirements in place since
2010, and there have been very few incidents in the United States since
then that plausibly raise openness concerns. It is telling that the two
most-discussed incidents that purportedly demonstrate the need for
conduct rules, concerning Madison River and Comcast/BitTorrent,
occurred before the Commission had in place an enforceable transparency
rule. And it was the disclosure, through complaints to the Commission
and media reports of the conduct at issue in those incidents, that led
to action against the challenged conduct.
223. As public access to information on ISP practices has
increased, there has been a shift toward ISPs resolving openness issues
themselves with less and less need for Commission intervention. In
2005, the Enforcement Bureau entered into a consent decree to resolve
the allegations against Madison River. In 2008, Comcast reached a
settlement with BitTorrent months before the Commission issued Comcast-
BitTorrent. By 2012, with a transparency rule in place, AT&T reversed
its blocking of access to FaceTime over its cellular network on certain
data plans of its own accord within approximately three months. This
trend toward swift ISP self-resolution comes, admittedly, from only a
few data points because, with transparency in place, almost no
incidents of harm to internet openness have arisen, suggesting that
ISPs are ``resolving'' issues by not letting them occur in the first
place.
224. We think the disinfectant of public scrutiny and market
pressure, not the threat of heavy-handed Commission regulation, best
explain the paucity of issues and their increasingly fast ISP-driven
resolution. Since the Commission adopted a transparency rule in the
Open Internet Order, conduct requirements have varied substantially,
from the rules adopted in the Open Internet Order, to no conduct rules
after the Verizon court case, to the rules adopted in the Title II
Order. Yet through all that time, the Commission released only one
Notice of Apparent Liability, against AT&T for allegedly violating the
transparency rule. The dearth of actions enforcing conduct rules is
striking. Further, the Title II Order and Open Internet Order do not,
and could not, claim an epidemic or even uptick of blocking or
degradation of traffic in the wake of the Comcast or Verizon court
decisions vacating the Commission's prior attempts at openness
regulation. These time periods provide a natural experiment disproving
the notion that conduct rules are necessary to promote openness. We
thus reject arguments to the contrary.
225. Although we think transparency promotes openness and empowers
consumers, we recognize that regulation has an important role to play
as a backstop where genuine harm is possible. In particular,
transparency amplifies the power of antitrust law and the FTC Act to
deter and where needed remedy behavior that harms consumers. While some
commenters assert that proof is difficult in antitrust proceedings, our
transparency rule requires ISPs to outline their business practices and
service offerings forthrightly and honestly. This requirement both
deters ISPs from engaging in anticompetitive, unfair, or deceptive
conduct and gives consumers and regulators the tools they need to take
action in the face of such behavior. Many ISPs have committed to abide
by open internet principles. By restoring authority to the FTC to take
action against deceptive ISP conduct, reclassification empowers the
expert consumer protection agency to exercise the authority granted to
them by Congress if ISPs fail to live up to their word and thereby harm
consumers.
226. Transparency thus leads to openness and achieves comparable
benefits to conduct rules. Moreover, the costs of compliance with a
transparency rule are much lower than the costs of compliance with
conduct rules. We therefore decline to impose this additional cost
given our view that transparency drives a free and open internet, and
in light of the FTC's and DOJ's authority to address any potential
harms. To the extent that conduct rules lead to any additional marginal
deterrence, we deem the substantial costs--including costs to consumers
in terms of lost innovation as well as monetary costs to ISPs--not
worth the possible benefits.
2. Costs of Conduct Rules Outweigh Benefits
a. General Conduct Rule
227. We find that the vague Internet Conduct Standard is not in the
public interest. Following adoption of this Order, the FTC will be able
to vigorously protect consumers and competition through its consumer
protection and antitrust authorities. Given this, we see little
incremental benefit and significant cost to retaining the Internet
Conduct Standard. The rule has created uncertainty and likely denied or
delayed consumer access to innovative new services, and we believe the
net benefit of the Internet Conduct Standard is negative. As such, we
find commenters urging the Commission to retain this standard, even
with modifications, unpersuasive.
228. Based on our experience with the rule and the extensive
record, we are persuaded that the Internet Conduct Standard is vague
and has created regulatory uncertainty in the marketplace hindering
investment and innovation. Because the Internet Conduct Standard is
vague, the standard and its implementing factors do not provide
carriers with adequate notice of what they are and are not permitted to
do, i.e., the standard does not afford parties a ``good process for
determining what conduct has actually been forbidden.'' The rule simply
warns carriers to behave in accordance with what the Commission might
require, without articulating any actual standard. Even ISP practices
based on consumer choice are not presumptively permitted; they are
merely ``less likely'' to violate the rule. Moreover, the uncertainty
caused by the Internet Conduct Standard goes far beyond what supporters
characterize as the flexibility that is necessary in a regulatory
structure to address future harmful behavior. We thus find that the
vague Internet Conduct Standard subjects providers to substantial
regulatory uncertainty and that the record before us demonstrates that
the Commission's predictive judgment in 2015 that this uncertainty was
``likely to be short term and will dissipate over time as the
marketplace internalizes [the] Title II approach'' has not been borne
out.
229. Increasing our concerns about the Internet Conduct Standard,
other agencies already have significant experience protecting against
the harms to competition and to consumers that the Internet Conduct
Standard purports to reach. The FTC, for example, has authority over
unfair and deceptive practices, both with respect to competition and
consumer protection.
[[Page 7898]]
We find that the FTC's authority over unfair and deceptive practices
and antitrust laws, with guidance from its ample body of precedent,
already provides the appropriate flexibility and predictability to
protect consumers and competition and addresses new practices that
might develop with less harm to innovation. We also observe that
because FTC and antitrust authority apply across industries, further
precedent is likely to develop more quickly, while a sector-specific
general conduct rule is likely to develop more slowly. While antitrust
laws use a consumer welfare standard defined by economic analysis to
evaluate harmful conduct, the Internet Conduct Standard includes a non-
exhaustive grab bag of considerations that are much broader and hazier
than the consumer welfare standard, and leaves the door open for the
Commission to consider other factors or unspecified conduct it would
like to take into account.
230. We anticipate that eliminating the vague Internet Conduct
Standard will reduce regulatory uncertainty and promote network
investment and service-related innovation. As we discussed above,
regulatory uncertainty serves as a major barrier to investment and
innovation. The record reflects that ISPs and edge providers of all
sizes have foregone and are likely to forgo or delay innovative service
offerings or different pricing plans that benefit consumers, citing
regulatory uncertainty under the Internet Conduct Standard in
particular. Indeed, these harms are not limited to ISPs--the rule
``creates paralyzing uncertainty for app developers and other edge
providers,'' as well as equipment manufacturers. Even some proponents
of Title II acknowledge these public interest harms. Commenters also
note that ``money spent on backward-looking regulatory compliance is
money not spent on more productive uses, such as investments in
broadband plant and services.'' We anticipate that eliminating the
Internet Conduct Standard will benefit consumers, increase competition,
and eliminate regulatory uncertainty that has ``a corresponding
chilling effect on broadband investment and innovation.''
231. The now-rescinded Zero-Rating Report issued by the Wireless
Telecommunications Bureau illustrates the uncertainty ISPs experience
as a result of the Internet Conduct Standard adopted in the Title II
Order. As described in the Report, ``zero-rated'' content,
applications, and services are those that end users can access without
the data consumed being counted toward the usage allowances or data
caps imposed by an operator's service plans. But following a thirteen-
month investigation during which providers were left uncertain about
whether their zero-rating practices complied with the Internet Conduct
Standard, the Report still did not identify specific evidence of harm
from particular zero-rating programs that increased the amount of data
that consumers could use or provide certainty about whether particular
zero-rating programs were legally permissible. Instead, it offered a
``set of overall considerations'' that it said would help ISPs assess
whether a particular zero-rating plan violates the Title II Order. The
now-rescinded Zero-Rating Report demonstrated that under the Internet
Conduct Standard ISPs have faced two options: Either wait for a
regulatory enforcement action that could arrive at some unspecified
future point or stop providing consumers with innovative offerings.
232. We anticipate that eliminating the vague Internet Conduct
Standard will also lower compliance and other related costs. The
uncertainty surrounding the rule ``establishes a standard for behavior
that virtually requires advice of counsel before a single decision is
made'' and raises ``costs [especially for smaller ISPs that] struggle
to understand its application to their service prices, terms,
conditions, and practices.'' Smaller ISPs contend that they cannot
``afford to be the subject of enforcement actions by the Commission or
defend themselves before the Commission as a result of consumer
complaints, because the costs of having to defend their actions before
the Commission in Washington are enormous, relative to their
resources.'' ISPs ``that are required to defend themselves against
arbitrary enforcement actions and/or frivolous complaints will not have
the time or financial resources to invest in their business. The costs
of such compliance will likely be passed onto consumers via higher
prices and/or limited service offerings and upgrades.'' The record
reflects widespread agreement from commenters with otherwise-divergent
views that the Internet Conduct Standard creates significant harm
without countervailing benefits.
233. We are further persuaded that the advisory opinion process
introduced in the Title II Order ``offers no real relief from the
unintended consequences of the Internet Conduct Standard.'' The record
reflects that the Internet Conduct Standard and the advisory opinions
available under it ``[are] completely divorced from the rapid pace of
innovation in the mobile marketplace'' because ISP innovations would be
indefinitely delayed while the Commission conducts a searching analysis
of any such offering that might violate the standard. The fact that no
ISP has requested an advisory opinion in the two years since the launch
of the advisory opinion process reinforces our conclusion that the
process is too uncertain and costly. As such, we reject commenters'
assertions to the contrary.
b. Paid Prioritization
234. We also decline to adopt a ban on paid prioritization. The
transparency rule we adopt, along with enforcement of the antitrust and
consumer protection laws, addresses many of the concerns regarding paid
prioritization raised in this record. Thus, the incremental benefit of
a ban on paid prioritization is likely to be small or zero. On the
other hand, we expect that eliminating the ban on paid prioritization
will help spur innovation and experimentation, encourage network
investment, and better allocate the costs of infrastructure, likely
benefiting consumers and competition. For these reasons and because we
find that eliminating the ban on paid prioritization arrangements could
lead to lower prices for consumers for broadband internet access
service, we find that our action benefits low-income communities and
non-profits, and we reject arguments to the contrary. We reject the
argument that the benefits of our elimination of the paid
prioritization ban must be ``uniform across providers or geographic
areas.'' This is an unnecessarily high and rigid threshold. The
public--including low-income communities--benefits, and that is enough.
Thus, the costs (forgone benefits) of the ban are likely significant
and outweigh any incremental benefits of a ban on paid prioritization.
235. Innovation. We anticipate that lifting the ban on paid
prioritization will increase network innovation, as the record
demonstrates that the ban on paid prioritization agreements has had,
and will continue to have, a chilling effect on network innovation
generally, and on the development of high quality-of-service (QoS)
arrangements--which require guarantees regarding packet loss, packet
delay, secure connectivity, and guaranteed bandwidth--in particular. As
CTIA argues, the Title II Order implicitly recognized this point, but
its insistence that these arrangements be treated as non-broadband
internet access data services reduced the flexibility of ISPs and edge
providers, created uncertainty about the line between non-broadband
internet access data services and broadband internet access services,
and likely reduced innovation. The record reflects that the
[[Page 7899]]
ban on paid prioritization has hindered the deployment of these
services by denying network operators the ability to price these
services, an important tool for appropriately allocating resources in a
market economy. We reject commenter assertions that banning the use of
price as a signal provides more accurate price signals. Relatedly, we
reject the argument that non-price signals, including user-directed
prioritization, are by themselves sufficient to allow innovation and
development in this area, because in a market system, price signals are
generally necessary to efficiently allocate resources. Further, as
commenters note, there has been significant uncertainty about the scope
of the prohibition on paid prioritization arrangements. Some commenters
contend that this uncertainty surrounding network operators' ability to
provide ``differentiated services'' has cast a shadow on the
development of next generation networks.
236. We also expect that ending the flat ban on paid prioritization
will encourage the entry of new edge providers into the market,
particularly those offering innovative forms of service differentiation
and experimentation. As ITTA explains, ``[i]t is routine for entities
that do business over the internet to pay for a variety of services to
provide an optimal user experience for their customers. Companies have
been doing so for years without disturbing the thriving internet
ecosystem.'' We therefore reject arguments that the ban is necessary to
provide a level playing field for edge providers. Indeed, in other
areas of the economy, paid prioritization has helped the entry of new
providers and brands. It is therefore no surprise that paid
prioritization has long been used throughout the economy. Paid
prioritization could allow small and new edge providers to compete on a
more even playing field against large edge providers, many of which
have CDNs and other methods of distributing their content quickly to
consumers. We thus reject arguments that allowing pro-competitive paid
prioritization will reduce the entry and expansion of small, new edge
providers. In so finding, we do not mean to suggest that CDN services
themselves constitute paid prioritization.
237. Efficiency. We find that a ban on paid prioritization is also
likely to reduce economic efficiency, also likely harming consumer
welfare. This finding is supported by the economic literature on two-
sided markets such as this one, and the record. If an ISP faces
competitive forces, a prohibition against two-sided pricing (i.e., a
zero-price rule), while benefiting edge providers, typically would harm
both subscribers and ISPs. Moreover, the level of harm to subscribers
and ISPs generally would exceed the gain obtained by the edge providers
and, thus, would lead to a reduction in total economic welfare. The
reasons for this are straightforward. Some edge services and their
associated end users use more data or require lower latency; this may
be the case, for example, with high-bandwidth applications such as
Netflix, which in the first half of 2016 generated more than a third of
all North American internet traffic. Without paid prioritization, ISPs
must recover these costs solely from end users, but ISPs cannot always
set prices targeted at the relevant end users. The resulting prices
create inefficiencies. Consumers who do not cause these costs must pay
for them, and end users who do cause these costs to some degree free-
ride, inefficiently distorting usage of both groups. When paid
prioritization signals to edge providers the costs their content or
applications cause, edge providers can undertake actions that would
improve the efficiency of the two-sided market. For example, they could
invest in compression technologies if those come at a lower cost than
paid prioritization, enhancing efficiency, or, if they have a pricing
relationship with their end users, they could directly charge the end
user for priority, leading those end users to adjust their usage if the
user's value does not exceed the service's cost, again enhancing
economic efficiency. We disagree with commenters asserting that this is
likely to significantly burden edge providers by requiring them to
negotiate with hundreds of ISPs because as discussed, paid
prioritization is likely to be focused only on applications that
require special QoS guarantees. And to the extent an ISP has market
power, antitrust and consumer protection laws could be used to address
ISPs' anti-competitive paid prioritization practices. Given the extent
of competition in internet access supply, we find a ban on paid
prioritization is unlikely to improve economic efficiency, and if it
were to do so it would only be by accident (i.e., if the efficient
second-best was to require ISPs to provide access to edge providers at
a zero price).
238. Network investment. The mere possibility that charging edge
providers may sometimes be economically inefficient is not sufficient
to overcome the general presumption that allowing firms additional
pricing tools generally enhances economic efficiency, especially when
investments must be made as demand rises to reduce congestion. The
economic literature and the record both suggest that paid
prioritization can increase network investment. For example, one study
presents a model in which two competing ISPs serve a continuum of edge
providers. It finds that allowing ISPs to offer paid prioritization
leads to higher investment in broadband capacity as well as greater
innovation on the edge provider side of the market. According to the
authors, paid prioritization causes the ISP to invest more in network
capacity, reducing congestion and thereby inducing congestion-sensitive
edge providers to enter the market. The increased ISP investment occurs
for two reasons: Incremental investment is more profitable because the
ISP can now charge edge providers in addition to subscribers, and paid
prioritization allows more edge providers who need a high quality of
service to enter the market. Another study also develops a theoretical
model in which paid prioritization always results in higher ISP
investment. We anticipate that lifting the ban on paid prioritization
may also increase the entry of new ISPs and encourage current providers
to expand their networks by making it easier for ``ISPs [to] benefit
from their new investments.'' Thus, we reject the argument that the ban
is necessary to ensure long-term network investment.
239. We reject assertions that allowing paid prioritization would
lead ISPs to create artificial scarcity on their networks by neglecting
or downgrading non-paid traffic. This argument has been strongly
criticized as having ``no support in economic theory that such
incentives exist or are sufficiently strong as to outweigh
countervailing incentives.'' Moreover, as discussed above, in practice
paid prioritization is likely to be used to deliver enhanced service
for applications that need QoS guarantees. As AT&T explains, ``[l]ast-
mile access is not a zero-sum game, and prioritizing the packets for
latency-sensitive applications will not typically degrade other
applications sharing the same infrastructure,'' such as email, software
updates, or cached video. We thus reject arguments premised on the
theory that ISPs could and would act to create artificial scarcity on
their networks and thereby broadly require paid prioritization. Because
of these practical limits on paid prioritization, we reject the
argument that non-profits and independent and diverse content
producers, who may be less likely to need QoS guarantees, will be
harmed by lifting the ban.
[[Page 7900]]
240. Reduction in price to consumers. Eliminating the ban on paid
prioritization arrangements could lead to lower prices for consumers
for broadband internet access service, as ISPs may be able to recoup
some of their costs from edge providers. Although we do not premise our
analysis on the expectation of a total pass-through of these revenues
to end-users, we find no support for assumptions that there would be no
pass-through of revenues at all. As one study explains, the Title II
Order's ban on paid prioritization arrangements ``can lead to higher
prices that are charged to all end users--regardless of whether or not
the end user subscribes to the content service that causes the
congestion.''
241. Closing the digital divide. Paid prioritization can also be a
tool in helping close the digital divide by reducing broadband internet
access service subscription prices for consumers. The zero-price rule
imposed by the blanket ban on paid prioritization ``imposes a
regressive subsidy, transferring wealth from the economically
disadvantaged to the comparatively rich by forcing the poor to support
high-bandwidth subscription services skewed towards the wealthier.''
One study concludes that ``[a]t the margin, this would cause the
lowest-end users to simply stop subscribing to internet services, which
would further exacerbate the existing digital divide.'' Accordingly,
economic ``models . . . suggest that network neutrality regulation is
more likely to worsen than improve the digital divide.'' Because ending
the ban on paid prioritization is likely to help close the digital
divide, we reject assertions to the contrary that ending the paid
prioritization rule's effective subsidization of high-bandwidth
services will harm consumers overall. We reject the contrary argument
that ISPs will engage in ``virtual redlining'' because, as discussed,
paid prioritization is likely to lead to increased network investment
and lower costs to end users, particularly benefiting those on the
wrong side of the digital divide. Allowing ISPs to charge both sides of
the market could also enable additional arrangements to provide special
low-cost broadband access, increasing broadband adoption among lower-
income consumers. For example, permitting ``differential pricing'' may
enable the development of ``[p]latforms that are both free and tailored
to [people without internet access],'' similar to Facebook's Free
Basics program in developing countries. Nokia suggests that ``a start-
up company that wants to reach new customers with a bandwidth intensive
application that will not work as intended below a certain service tier
. . . should be allowed to offer to boost [a] consumer's bandwidth so
he or she can experience their product as intended,'' and argues such
arrangements ``are most likely to benefit lower-income consumers, since
those that already purchase high-tier services are less likely to
benefit from third-party-pays QoS enhancements.''
242. Addressing Harms. We find that antitrust law, in combination
with the transparency rule we adopt, is particularly well-suited to
addressing any potential or actual anticompetitive harms that may arise
from paid prioritization arrangements. The transparency rule will
require ISPs to disclose any practices that favor some internet traffic
over other traffic, if the practices are paid or benefit any affiliated
entity. The transparency rule will provide greater information to all
participants in the internet ecosystem and empower them to act if they
identify any potential anticompetitive conduct. Antitrust law is
ideally situated to determine whether a specific arrangement, on
balance, is anti-competitive or pro-competitive. We therefore reject
the argument that the paid prioritization ban should be modified to
more squarely focus on anticompetitive conduct. While these alternative
formulations may not be as problematic as the blanket ban, for the
reasons discussed above, antitrust law is better placed than ex ante
regulations to balance the potential benefits and harms of new
arrangements. Moreover, to the extent that they exist, the potential
harms to internet openness stemming from paid prioritization
arrangements are outweighed by the distortions that banning paid
prioritization would impose. Under the antitrust laws, a paid
prioritization agreement challenged as anticompetitive would be
evaluated under the case-specific rule of reason. Paid prioritization
would be prohibited only when it harms competition, for example, by
inappropriately favoring an affiliate or partner in a way that
ultimately harms economic competition in the relevant market. The case-
by-case, deliberative nature of antitrust is well-suited for this area,
as it is difficult to determine on an ex ante basis which paid
prioritization agreements are anticompetitive, and in fact, no internet
paid prioritization agreements have yet been launched in the United
States, rendering any concerns about such practices purely theoretical
at this time. We therefore reject arguments that ex ante rules are
preferable.
243. Lastly, antitrust laws would not prevent an ISP from
exercising legally-acquired market power to earn market rents, so long
as it is not used anticompetitively, but we do not consider any harms
that might result from this to be so large as to justify the harms that
a total prohibition on paid prioritization would entail. For harms from
the exercise of legally-acquired market power to arise, the ISP must
have market power over the edge provider. However, as shown above, ISPs
usually face at least moderate competition, and all the more so taking
a medium-term perspective. Consequently, the harms that could possibly
occur from exercise of such power are not likely to be large. Further,
the extent to which any harms actually occur will be muted by two
factors. First, ISPs have strong incentives to keep edge provider
output high (as this increases the value end users see in subscribing
to the ISP, and signals to edge providers that the ISP recognizes their
contribution to the platform). Thus, harm will only occur to the extent
the ISP is unable to devise pricing schemes that preserve edge
providers' incentives to bring content while maximizing the ISP's
profit (the exercise of market power is only harmful when it excludes
what would otherwise be efficient purchases of access). Second, as
discussed above, increased prices from edge providers are to a
potentially significant extent passed through to end users in the form
of lower prices for broadband internet access service, with the result
that end user demand for edge provider content is increased. The extent
of such pass-through offsets these harms. Accordingly, we expect the
harms from dictating pricing uniformity to edge providers exceed any
harms that may emerge from a lack of such regulation.
c. Blocking and Throttling
244. We find the no-blocking and no-throttling rules are
unnecessary to prevent the harms that they were intended to thwart. We
find that the transparency rule we adopt today--coupled with our
enforcement authority and with FTC enforcement of ISP commitments,
antitrust law, consumer expectations, and ISP incentives--will be
sufficient to prevent these harms, particularly given the consensus
against blocking practices, as reflected in the scarcity of actual
cases of such blocking. For the same reasons, we reject alternative
formulations of the no-blocking and no-throttling rules.
245. Transparency rule. As discussed above, the transparency rule
we adopt, combined with antitrust and consumer
[[Page 7901]]
protection laws, obviate the need for conduct rules by achieving
comparable benefits at lower cost. In addition, several factors
specific to blocking and throttling will work to prevent the potential
harms that could be caused by blocking and throttling. First, most
attempts by ISPs to block or throttle content will likely be met with a
fierce consumer backlash. As one commenter explains, such blocking or
throttling is ``unlikely to occur, because it must be sufficiently
blatant to be of any benefit to the ISP, that [it] only increases the
likelihood of getting caught.'' Second, numerous ISPs, including the
four largest fixed ISPs, have publicly committed not to block or
throttle the content that consumers choose. The transparency rule will
ensure that ISPs reveal any deviation from these commitments to the
public, and addresses commenter concerns that consumers will not
understand the source of any blocking or throttling. Violations of the
transparency rule will be subject to our enforcement authority.
Furthermore, the FTC possesses the authority to enforce these
commitments, as it did in TracFone. Third, the antitrust laws prohibit
anticompetitive conduct, and to the extent blocking or throttling by an
ISP may constitute such conduct, the existence of these laws likely
deters potentially anticompetitive conduct. Finally, ISPs have long-
term incentives to preserve internet openness, which creates demand for
the internet access service that they provide.
246. Consensus against blocking and throttling. We emphasize once
again that we do not support blocking lawful content, consistent with
long-standing Commission policy. The potential consequences of blocking
or throttling lawful content on the internet ecosystem are well-
documented in the record and in Commission precedent. Stakeholders from
across the internet ecosystem oppose the blocking and throttling of
lawful content, including ISPs, public interest groups, edge providers,
other content producers, network equipment manufacturers, government
entities, and other businesses and individuals who use the internet.
This consensus is among the reasons that there is scant evidence that
end users, under different legal frameworks, have been prevented by
blocking or throttling from accessing the content of their choosing. It
also is among the reasons why providers have voluntarily abided by no-
blocking practices even during periods where they were not legally
required to do so. As to free expression in particular, we note that
none of the actual incidents discussed in the Title II Order squarely
implicated free speech. If anything, recent evidence suggests that
hosting services, social media platforms, edge providers, and other
providers of virtual internet infrastructure are more likely to block
content on viewpoint grounds. Furthermore, in the event that any
stakeholder were inclined to deviate from this consensus against
blocking and throttling, we fully expect that consumer expectations,
market incentives, and the deterrent threat of enforcement actions will
constrain such practices ex ante. To the extent that these incentives
prove insufficient and any stakeholder engages in such conduct, such
practices can be policed ex post by antitrust and consumer protection
agencies.
247. Additionally, as urged by the prior Commission when defending
the Title II Order, and as confirmed in the concurrence in the denial
of rehearing en banc by the two judges in the majority in USTelecom,
the Title II Order allows ISPs to offer curated services, which would
allow ISPs to escape the reach of the Title II Order and to filter
content on viewpoint grounds. In practice, the Title II Order
``deregulates curated Internet access relative to conventional Internet
access [and] may induce ISPs to filter content more often,'' rendering
the no-blocking and no-throttling rules ineffectual as long as an ISP
disclosed it was offering curated services. The curated services
exemption arising from the Title II Order confirms our judgment that
transparency requirements, rather than conduct rules, are the most
effective means of preserving internet openness.
3. The Record Does Not Identify Authority for Comprehensive Conduct
Rules
248. The record in this proceeding does not persuade us that there
are any sources of statutory authority that individually, or in the
aggregate, could support conduct rules uniformly encompassing all ISPs.
We find that provisions in Section 706 of the 1996 Act directing the
Commission to encourage deployment of advanced telecommunications
capability are better interpreted as hortatory rather than as
independent grants of regulatory authority. We also are not persuaded
that Section 230 of the Communications Act is a grant of regulatory
authority that could provide the basis for conduct rules here. Nor does
the record here reveal other sources of authority that collectively
would provide a sure foundation for conduct rules that would treat all
similarly-situated ISPs the same.
a. Section 706 of the 1996 Act
249. We conclude that the directives to the Commission in Section
706(a) and (b) of the 1996 Act to promote deployment of advanced
telecommunications capability are better interpreted as hortatory, and
not as grants of regulatory authority. We thus depart from the
interpretation of those provisions adopted by the Commission beginning
in the Open Internet Order, and return to a reading of that language in
Section 706 of the 1996 Act consistent with the Commission's original
interpretation.
250. We adopt this reading in light of the text, structure, and
history of the 1996 Act and Communications Act. Section 706(a) directs
that:
The Commission and each State commission with regulatory
jurisdiction over telecommunications services shall encourage the
deployment on a reasonable and timely basis of advanced
telecommunications capability to all Americans (including, in
particular, elementary and secondary schools and classrooms) by
utilizing, in a manner consistent with the public interest,
convenience, and necessity, price cap regulation, regulatory
forbearance, measures that promote competition in the local
telecommunications market, or other regulating methods that remove
barriers to infrastructure investment.
In turn, Section 706(b) provides in pertinent part that ``[i]f the
Commission's determination'' under an annual inquiry into deployment of
advanced telecommunications capability ``is negative, it shall take
immediate action to accelerate deployment of such capability by
removing barriers to infrastructure investment and by promoting
competition in the telecommunications market.''
251. The relevant text of Section 706(a) and (b) of the 1996 Act is
reasonably read as exhorting the Commission to exercise market-based or
deregulatory authority granted under other statutory provisions,
particularly the Communications Act. The Commission otherwise has
authority under the Communications Act to employ price cap regulation
for services subject to rate regulation; to employ regulatory
forbearance; to promote competition in the local telecommunications
market; and to remove barriers to infrastructure investment. The
Commission thus need not interpret Section 706 as an independent grant
of regulatory authority to give those provisions meaning. Further,
consistent with
[[Page 7902]]
normal canons of statutory interpretation, the language ``other
regulating methods'' in Section 706(a) is best understood as consistent
with the language that precedes it, and thus likewise reasonably is
read as focused on the exercise of other statutory authority like that
under the Communications Act, rather than itself constituting an
independent grant of regulatory authority. This view also comports with
the Commission's original interpretation of the language of Section
706(a), avoids rendering the provisions of Section 706(a) or (b)
surplusage, and does not otherwise conflict with the statutory text.
Although the term ``shall'' ``generally indicates a command that admits
of no discretion,'' because the Commission has other authority under
the Communications Act that it can exercise consistent with the
direction in Section 706(a) and (b) of the 1996 Act, our interpretation
is not at odds with the use of ``shall encourage'' in Section 706(a) or
``shall take immediate action'' in Section 706(b). In particular,
Section 706(a) provides a general, ongoing exhortation for the
Commission to encourage deployment of advanced telecommunications
capability through exercise of other authority, while Section 706(b)
directs the Commission to do so by taking ``immediate action'' in the
event of a negative finding under the Section 706(b) inquiry. The
direction in Section 706(b) of the 1996 Act that the Commission
exercise other authority by taking ``immediate action'' in the event of
a negative finding under the Section 706(b) inquiry could, for example,
form part of the basis for petition(s) for Commission rulemaking based
on such other authority in the wake of a negative finding in the
Section 706(b) inquiry. Although the Tenth Circuit concluded that the
possibility of such an interpretation of Section 706(b) would not
unambiguously compel the conclusion that the provision is hortatory,
the court's decision does not limit our ability to rely on that as a
factor that persuades us that Section 706(b) is better read as
hortatory.
252. We not only find that the relevant language in Sections 706(a)
and (b) of the 1996 Act permissibly can be read as hortatory, but are
persuaded that is the better interpretation. Arguments in the record
supporting Section 706 of the 1996 Act as granting regulatory authority
generally contend that this is a permissible interpretation but do not
persuade us it is the better reading. For one, although the relevant
provisions in Section 706(a) and (b) identify certain regulatory tools
(like price cap regulation and regulatory forbearance) and marketplace
outcomes (like increased competition and reduced barriers to
infrastructure investment), they nowhere identify the providers or
entities whose conduct could be regulated under Section 706 if
interpreted as a grant of such authority. This lack of detail stands in
stark contrast to Congress's approach in many other provisions enacted
or modified as part of the 1996 Act that clearly are grants of
authority to employ similar regulatory tools or pursue similar
marketplace outcomes and that directly identify the relevant providers
or entities subject to the exercise of that regulatory authority. The
absence of any similar language in Section 706(a) and (b) of the 1996
Act supports our view that those provisions are better read as
directing the Commission regarding its exercise of regulatory authority
granted elsewhere. Our consideration of this as one factor persuading
us that Section 706 of the 1996 Act is better read as hortatory is not
undercut by our reliance on Section 257 as authority for disclosure
requirements that provide us information needed to identify potential
barriers to entry and investment while also helping mitigate any such
barriers. Although Section 257 does not expressly identify entities
from which we can obtain information, other aspects of Section 257
persuade us that our interpretation of that provision as a grant of
authority to obtain the information we require from ISPs is necessary
for us to carry out our duties under that provision for the reasons
discussed above. Here, by contrast, this consideration combines with
many others to collectively persuade us that Section 706 of the 1996
Act is better read as hortatory.
253. Indeed, under the Open Internet Order's theory of Section
706(a) and (b) as independent grants of authority, the Commission could
rely on those provisions to impose duties or adopt regulations
equivalent to those directly addressed by the provisions of the
Communications Act focused on promoting competition and/or deployment
that go beyond the entities, contexts, and circumstances that bounded
the Communications Act provisions. Section 706(a) and (b) direct the
Commission to promote competition in the local telecommunications
market and otherwise encourage the deployment of advanced
telecommunications capability. Promoting local competition and/or
encouraging the deployment of telecommunications networks likewise are
key objectives of a number of provisions added to the Communications
Act by the 1996 Act, each of which were limited in scope to address the
actions of particular, defined entities and were triggered in
particular, defined circumstances. For example, the 1996 Act amended
Section 224 of the Communications Act to expand specified
communications providers' access to utilities' poles, ducts, conduit,
and rights-of-way to ``ensure that the deployment of communications
networks and the development of competition are not impeded by private
ownership and control of the scarce infrastructure and rights-of-way
that many communications providers must use in order to reach
customers.'' The market-opening framework in Sections 251(a)-(c), 252,
and 271 of the Communications Act, applicable respectively to
telecommunications carriers, LECs, incumbent LECs, and BOCs, also were
added by the 1996 Act. The 1996 Act also added provisions to the
Communications Act to eliminate regulatory barriers to competition and
network deployment in certain defined circumstances. We are skeptical
that at the same time Congress enacted carefully-tailored regulatory
regimes codified in various provisions of the Communications Act, it
simultaneously granted the Commission redundant authority to impose
those same duties or adopt similar regulatory treatment largely unbound
by that tailoring in a ``Miscellaneous'' provision of the same
legislation.
254. Our interpretation of Section 706 of the 1996 Act as hortatory
also is supported by the implications of the Open Internet Order's
interpretation for the regulatory treatment of the internet and
information services more generally. The interpretation of Section
706(a) and (b) that the Commission adopted beginning in the Open
Internet Order reads those provisions to grant authority for the
Commission to regulate information services so long as doing so could
be said to encourage deployment of advanced telecommunications
capability at least indirectly. A reading of Section 706 as a grant of
regulatory authority that could be used to heavily regulate information
services--as under the Commission's prior interpretation--is undercut
by what the Commission has found to be Congress' intent in other
provisions of the Communications Act enacted in the 1996 Act--namely,
to distinguish between telecommunications services and information
services, with the latter left largely unregulated by default.
[[Page 7903]]
255. In addition, the 1996 Act added Section 230 of the
Communications Act, which provides, among other things, that ``[i]t is
the policy of the United States . . . to preserve the vibrant and
competitive free market that presently exists for the internet and
other interactive computer services, unfettered by Federal or State
regulation.'' The Open Internet Order asserted that ``[m]aximizing end-
user control is a policy goal Congress recognized in Section 230(b) of
the Communications Act.'' In full, however, Section 230(b)(3) states
that ``[i]t is the policy of the United States--. . . to encourage the
development of technologies which maximize user control over what
information is received by individuals, families, and schools who use
the Internet and other interactive computer services.'' Although the
rules in the Open Internet Order would have considered the extent to
which a network management practice is subject to end-user control when
evaluating the reasonableness of discrimination, that Order does not
explain why that (or conduct rules more generally) would better
encourage the development of technologies for end-user control than
would be the case without such rules. The Title II Order is similar in
this regard. Assertions of the sort in those Orders thus provide no
basis for concluding that regulating ISPs is likely to better
``encourage the development of technologies which maximize user
control'' than the absence of such regulations. A necessary implication
of the prior interpretation of Section 706(a) and (b) as grants of
regulatory authority is that the Commission could regulate not only
ISPs but also edge providers or other participants in the internet
marketplace--even when they constitute information services, and
notwithstanding Section 230 of the Communications Act--so long as the
Commission could find at least an indirect nexus to promoting the
deployment of advanced telecommunications capability. For example, some
commenters argue that ``it is content aggregators (think Netflix, Etsy,
Google, Facebook) that probably exert the greatest, or certainly the
most direct, influence over access.'' Section 230 likewise is in
tension with the view that Section 706(a) and (b) grant the Commission
regulatory authority as the Commission previously claimed. These
inconsistencies are avoided, however, if the deployment directives of
Section 706(a) and (b) are viewed as hortatory.
256. Prior Commission guidance regarding how it would interpret and
apply the authority it claimed under Section 706(a) and (b) of the 1996
Act does not allay our concerns with the interpretation of those
provisions as grants of regulatory authority. For example, the Open
Internet Order stated that Section 706 authority only would be used to
regulate ``communication by wire or radio,'' consistent with Sections 1
and 2 of the Communications Act. Other provisions enacted in the 1996
Act that clearly grant authority to promote competition or network
deployment themselves generally address either facilities being used to
engage in communications or the communications themselves, however.
Thus, applying Section 706 of the 1996 Act only to communication by
wire or radio would not prevent the Commission from replicating such
requirements. In addition, broadband internet access service itself
involves communications by wire or radio--as do many other internet
information services. Consequently, this Commission guidance also does
not resolve tensions between the Commission's prior theory of Section
706 authority and the 1996 Act's general deregulatory approach to
information services or Section 230's enunciation of the federal policy
``to preserve the vibrant and competitive free market that presently
exists for the Internet and other interactive computer services,
unfettered by Federal or State regulation.''
257. Nor are the specific, problematic implications we identify
with the Commission's prior interpretation of Section 706 as a grant of
authority avoided by the Commission's explanation that its use of such
authority must encourage the deployment of advanced telecommunications
capability by promoting competition or removing barriers to
infrastructure investment. Given the already-recognized nexus between
the relevant Communications Act provisions and the promotion of network
deployment and/or local competition, the record provides no reason to
believe the Commission would have difficulty demonstrating at least an
indirect effect on the deployment of advanced telecommunications
capability should it wish, as a policy matter, to impose equivalent
requirements under an assertion of authority under Section 706(a) and
(b) without adhering to limitations or constraints present in the
Communications Act provisions. Perhaps if the Commission required a
tighter connection between a given regulatory action and promoting
deployment of advanced telecommunications capability, it might reduce
the magnitude of the inconsistency somewhat, but the record does not
reveal that such an approach would eliminate it entirely or even
diminish it to such an extent as to materially strengthen the argument
for interpreting the relevant provisions of Section 706(a) and (b) as
grants of regulatory authority. Such proposals also do not address the
other reasons for viewing Sections 706(a) and (b) as hortatory in light
of the statutory text and structure. Likewise, the Open Internet Order
shows that the Commission can readily find that criterion met in order
to regulate an information service like broadband internet access
service notwithstanding the 1996 Act's general deregulatory approach
for information service and the deregulatory internet policy specified
in Section 230 of the Act.
258. Guidance in the Open Internet Order also asserted that the
exercise of Section 706 authority could not be ``inconsistent with
other provisions of law,'' but effectively viewed that as a very low
bar to satisfy, finding it reasonable to exercise Section 706 authority
to impose duties on information service providers that did not
meaningfully ``differ[ ] from the nondiscrimination standard applied to
common carriers generally.'' So long as regulations fall outside the
constraints of Sections 3(51) and 332(c)(2) of the Act--upon which the
reversal in Verizon was based--neither precedent nor the record here
demonstrate that the reference to ensuring that any Section 706
authority be exercised ``[ ]consistent with other provisions of law''
would meaningfully preclude the types of requirements that we find
difficult to square with the carefully tailored authority in the
Communications Act. Conversely, if the fact that a matter is addressed
by the Communications Act were a more serious constraint on claimed
Section 706(a) and (b) authority, it is unclear how meaningful such
claimed authority would be in practice. It thus likewise would be
unclear what affirmative reason we would have for interpreting them as
grants of authority contrary to the other indicia that they are
hortatory. For example, Sections 201(b) and 202(a) of the Act prohibit
unjust and unreasonable rates and practices and unjust an unreasonable
discrimination with respect to common carrier services. If that
precluded reliance on Section 706(a) and (b) to impose analogous
restrictions unbounded by the self-described scope of Sections 201(b)
and
[[Page 7904]]
202(a), the Commission seemingly would be left with no authority to
adopt conduct rules of the sort at issue here after reclassification.
Nor do commenters citing other possible uses of Section 706(a) and (b)
as authority explain how such exercise of authority could be reconciled
with the view that it would be a serious constraint on claimed Section
706(a) and (b) authority if a matter is addressed by the Communications
Act (such as in Sections 201 and 202, the market-opening provisions in
Sections 251-261, provisions designed to address barriers to
infrastructure deployment like Sections 224 and 254, or other
provisions). Thus, interpreting the Communications Act as a more
serious constraint might partially address one basis for interpreting
Section 706(a) and (b) as hortatory, but simultaneously would undercut
the arguments in the record for interpreting them as grants of
authority.
259. We also are unpersuaded by the Open Internet Order's citation
of legislative history to support its interpretation of Section 706(a)
and (b) as grants of regulatory authority. The Open Internet Order
cited a Senate report for the proposition that those provisions of
Section 706 ``are `a necessary fail-safe' to guarantee that Congress's
objective is reached.'' The Commission itself previously noted the
ambiguous significance of that language. In addition, the relevant
Senate bill at the time of the Senate report would have directed the
Commission, in the event of a negative finding in its deployment
inquiry, to ``take immediate action under this section'' and stated
that ``it may preempt State commissions that fail to act to ensure such
availability.'' The final, enacted version of Section 706(b), by
contrast, omitted the language ``under this section,'' and also omitted
the express preemption language, leaving it ambiguous whether the
statement in the Senate report was premised on statutory language
excluded from the enacted provision. For its part, the conference
report neither repeats the ``fail-safe'' language from the Senate
report nor elaborates on the modifications made to the language in the
Senate bill. Even if it were appropriate to consult legislative
history, we conclude that that history is ultimately ambiguous and are
not persuaded that it supports interpreting Section 706(a) and (b) of
the 1996 Act as grants of regulatory authority.
260. The inability to impose penalties to enforce violations of
requirements adopted under Section 706(a) and (b) of the 1996 Act also
undercuts arguments that those provisions should be interpreted as
grants of regulatory authority. Section 706 of the 1996 Act was not
incorporated into the Communications Act, nor does the 1996 Act provide
for it to be enforced as part of the Communications Act. Where Congress
intended a statute outside the Communications Act to be enforced as if
it were part of the Communications Act, it has expressly stated that in
the relevant statute. Thus, the Communications Act provisions generally
authorizing penalties do not apply to Section 706 of the 1996 Act or
rules adopted thereunder. In pertinent part, to enforce rules under
Section 503(b)(1) of the Communications Act, the rules must be ``issued
by the Commission under [the Communications] Act.'' Other penalty
provisions in the Communications Act are specific to narrower topics or
the statutory section in which they appear, and thus also would not be
authorized penalties for violations of rules implementing Section 706
of the 1996 Act. Although the Title II Order claimed that Section 706
of the 1996 Act included an implicit grant of enforcement authority,
even under that theory, an `implicit' grant of enforcement authority
might enable actions like declaratory rulings or cease-and-desist
orders, but would not appear to encompass authority to impose penalties
given the absence of statutory language clearly granting that
authority. As a fallback, the Title II Order asserted, without
elaboration, that by relying on the grant of rulemaking authority in
Section 4(i) of the Communications Act to adopt rules implementing
Section 706 of the 1996 Act, the resulting rules would be within the
scope of those for which forfeitures could be imposed under the
Communications Act.
261. We believe that the better view is that reliance on the
Communications Act for rulemaking authority alone would not render the
resulting rules ``issued by the Commission under [the Communications]
Act'' as required to trigger the forfeiture provisions of Section 503
of the Act. Given that Section 503 is about enforcement consequences
from violating standards of conduct specified by, among other things,
relevant Commission rules, we think that language is best read as
focused on rules implementing the Commission's substantive regulatory
authority under the Communications Act. Insofar as the substantive
standard to which an entity is being held flows not from the
Communications Act but from the Commission's assertion of authority
under the 1996 Act, we believe that our forfeiture authority under
Section 503 of the Communications Act consequently would not encompass
such rules. The practical inability to back up rules implementing
Section 706 with penalties thus undercuts the Open Internet Order's
claim that its interpretation would mean that Section 706 of the 1996
Act could serve as a `` `fail safe' that `ensures' the Commission's
ability to promote advanced services.'' Under our interpretation, by
contrast, Section 706(a) and (b) of the 1996 Act exhort the Commission
to use Communications Act authority that it does, in fact, have
authority to enforce through penalties. We thus are persuaded that
Section 706(a) and (b) of the 1996 Act are better interpreted as
hortatory, rather than as grants of regulatory authority. Because we
otherwise find ample grounds to conclude that Section 706(a) and (b) of
the 1996 Act are not grants of regulatory authority, we need not, and
thus do not, address arguments claiming additional reasons to reach
that same conclusion. Likewise, because we conclude that Section 706(a)
and (b) do not grant regulatory authority at all, we need not, and do
not, address the issue of whether any authority under those provisions
is, at most, deregulatory authority. We also reject arguments that we
should wait on the completion of the latest inquiry under Section
706(b) before evaluating the interpretation of Section 706. Under the
prior interpretation, Section 706(a) was a grant of authority
independent of Section 706(b), and particularly insofar as we would not
interpret Section 706(b) as a grant of authority in any case, we see no
reason to wait on the results of the inquiry under that provision.
262. Our conclusion that Section 706 of the 1996 Act is better read
as hortatory is not at odds with the fact that two courts concluded
that the Commission permissibly could adopt the alternative view that
it is a grant of regulatory authority. Those courts did not find that
the Commission's previous reading was the only (or even the most)
reasonable interpretation of Section 706, leaving the Commission free
to adopt a different interpretation upon further consideration. Indeed,
the DC Circuit in Verizon observed that the language of Section 706(a)
``certainly could be read'' as hortatory. The court also recognized as
much with respect to Section 706(b), given its lack of clarity. Those
cases thus leave us free to act on our conclusion here that Section 706
is most reasonably read as hortatory, not as an independent grant of
regulatory authority.
[[Page 7905]]
263. We also disagree with arguments that we should keep in place a
misguided and flawed interpretation of Section 706(a) and (b) of the
1996 Act to preserve any existing rules or our ability going forward to
take regulatory action based on such assertions of authority. We are
not persuaded by concerns that reinterpreting Section 706(a) and (b) of
the 1996 Act in this manner could undercut Commission rules adopted in
other contexts because such arguments do not identify circumstances--
nor are we otherwise aware of any--where the prior interpretation of
the relevant provisions of Section 706(a) and/or (b) was, in whole or
in part, a necessary basis for the rules. Similarly, concerns that our
interpretation will limit states' regulatory authority do not identify
with specificity any concrete need for such authority beyond any
authority provided by state law, even assuming arguendo that such
authority could have flowed from the prior interpretation of Section
706(a). MMTC and NABOB express concerns that disavowing Section 706 as
a source of authority could constrain the Commission's ability to
address ``digital redlining.'' They do not explain, however, why other
statutory provisions such as Section 254 are inadequate to address
issues of unserved or underserved communities should more ultimately be
found to be needed beyond the Commission's other efforts to promote
broadband deployment more generally. We also are unpersuaded by
arguments for maintaining the prior interpretation in a general effort
to retain greater authority to regulate ISPs. Given that agencies like
the Commission are creatures of Congress, and given our responsibility
to bring to bear appropriate tools when interpreting and implementing
the statutes we administer, we find it more appropriate to adopt what
we view as the far better interpretation of Section 706(a) and (b)
given both the specific context of Section 706 and the broader
statutory context. If Congress wishes to give the Commission more
explicit direction to impose certain conduct rules on ISPs, or to
impose such rules itself within constitutional limits, it is of course
free to do so. We decline to read such wide-ranging authority, however,
into provisions that, on our reading today, are merely hortatory, and
are at best ambiguous.
264. Independently, we also are not persuaded that the prior
interpretation of Section 706(a) and (b) of the 1996 Act would better
advance policy goals relevant here. We have other sources of authority
on which to ground our transparency requirements without adopting an
inferior interpretation of Section 706(a) and (b). With respect to
conduct rules, in addition to our decision that limits on our legal
authority counsel against adopting such rules, we separately find that
such rules are not otherwise justified by the record here.
Consequently, we need not stretch the words of Section 706 of the 1996
Act because we can protect internet freedom even without it. Rather, we
are persuaded to act in the manner that we believe reflects the best
interpretation given the text and structure of the Act, the legislative
history, and the policy implications of alternative interpretations.
b. Section 230 of the Communications Act
265. We are not persuaded that Section 230 of the Communications
Act grants the Commission authority that could provide the basis for
conduct rules here. In Comcast, the DC Circuit observed that the
Commission there ``acknowledge[d] that Section 230(b)'' is a
``statement [ ] of policy that [itself] delegate[s] no regulatory
authority.'' Although the Internet Freedom NPRM sought comment on
Section 230, the record does not reveal an alternative interpretation
that would enable us to rely on it as a grant of regulatory authority
for rules here. Instead, we remain persuaded that Section 230(b) is
hortatory, directing the Commission to adhere to the policies specified
in that provision when otherwise exercising our authority. In addition,
even assuming arguendo that Section 230 could be viewed as a grant of
Commission authority, we are not persuaded it could be invoked to
impose regulatory obligations on ISPs. In particular, Section 230(b)(2)
provides that it is U.S. policy ``to preserve the vibrant and
competitive free market that presently exists for the internet and
other interactive computer services, unfettered by Federal or State
regulation.'' Adopting requirements that would impose federal
regulation on broadband internet access service would be in tension
with that policy, and we thus are skeptical such requirements could be
justified by Section 230 even if it were a grant of authority as
relevant here. Consequently, although Section 230 is relevant to our
interpretation and implementation of other statutory provisions, the
record does not reveal a basis for relying on it as a source of
regulatory authority for conduct rules here.
c. Other Provisions in Titles II, III, and VI of the Communications Act
266. Other identified sources of potential authority appear
significantly limited and not capable of bringing all ISPs under one
comprehensive regulatory framework. The Open Internet Order cited
provisions in Titles II, III, and VI of the Communications Act in
support of the conduct rules adopted there, and some commenters echo
those theories--generally without elaboration. Some comments identified
possible sources of authority for rules other than the sorts of conduct
rules at issue in this proceeding, and we do not discuss such other
sources of authority here. We also are not persuaded by claims that
Section 1 of the Act is a grant of regulatory authority here. In this
very context, the DC Circuit has held that Section 1 is better
understood as a statement of Congressional policy. A number of those
assertions of authority appear of uncertain validity on this record.
The identified additional sources of potential authority, even
collectively, do not appear to provide a sound basis for conduct rules
that would encompass all ISPs. We do not formally resolve the potential
scope and contours of those claims of authority given the significant
limitations in the record here and the potential for unanticipated
spill-over effects, but the potential weaknesses--unresolved on this
record--nonetheless make us cautious about seeking to rely on them at
this time. Insofar as our position regarding these additional potential
sources of authority is at least a partial change in course from the
positions taken in the Open Internet Order--which reflected a broader
and/or less questioning view of these theories--we conclude that such a
change in course is warranted by our analysis here, which identifies
details or nuances in the required analysis that were not adequately
addressed in the Open Internet Order or resolved on this record.
Further, even as to those ISPs that could be subject to conduct rules
under those statutory theories, in many cases the scope of conduct that
could be addressed appears quite limited. The result of an attempt to
exercise the identified potential authority thus would appear, at best,
to result in a patchwork framework that appears unlikely to materially
address many of the concerns historically raised to justify conduct
rules while being likely to introduce regulatory distortions in the
marketplace.
267. Authority over ISPs That Also Offer Telecommunications
Services. On this record, claims of authority to adopt
[[Page 7906]]
conduct rules governing ISPs that also offer telecommunications
services have many shortcomings. The Open Internet Order contended that
ISPs that also offer telecommunications services might engage in
network management practices or prioritization that reduces competition
for their voice services, arguably implicating Section 201(b)'s
prohibition on unjust or unreasonable rates or practices in the case of
common carrier voice services and/or Section 251(a)(1)'s
interconnection requirements for common carriers. The Open Internet
Order never squares these legal theories with the statutory prohibition
on treating telecommunications carriers as common carriers when they
are not engaged in the provision of telecommunications service or with
the similar restriction on common carrier treatment of private mobile
services. That Order also is ambiguous whether it is relying on these
provisions for direct or ancillary authority. If claiming direct
authority, the Open Internet Order fails to reconcile its theories with
relevant precedent and to address key factual questions. With respect
to Section 201, in the Computer Inquiries, for example, when the
Commission concluded that facilities-based carriers' actions when
offering enhanced services might affect the justness and reasonableness
of their common carrier offerings under Section 201, it responded by
exercising ancillary authority, rather than direct authority under
Section 201. With respect to Section 251(a)(1), the Commission has held
that that provision only involves the linking of networks and not the
transport and termination of traffic. The Open Internet Order does not
explain why telecommunications carriers would seek to link their
networks with other carriers by delivering traffic through a broadband
internet access service rather than through normal means of direct or
indirect interconnection. Even in the more likely case that these
represented theories of ancillary authority, the Open Internet Order's
failure to forthrightly engage with the theories on those terms leaves
it unclear how conduct rules are sufficiently ``necessary'' to the
implementation of Section 201 and/or Section 251(a)(1) to satisfy the
standard for ancillary authority under Comcast. The limited, indirect
references to Section 201 and 251(a)(1) authority in the record here do
not resolve these questions about possible Section 201- or 251(a)(1)-
based theories, either.
268. The Open Internet Order also noted that Section 256 of the Act
addresses coordinated network planning related to interconnection, but
did not put forward a theory for relying on that as authority for
conduct rule. To the contrary, it cited the holding in Comcast
``acknowledging Section 256's objective, while adding that Section 256
does not `expand[ ] . . . any authority that the Commission[ ]
otherwise has under law.' '' To the extent that commenters here mention
Section 256 at all, they do not explain how the Commission could
overcome that holding in Comcast for purposes of relying on that
provision as authority for rules here.
269. An alarm company urges us to rely on Section 275 of the Act,
but we see substantial shortcomings in using as a basis for ancillary
authority for conduct rules. Section 275 of the Act imposes certain
nondiscrimination requirements on incumbent LECs related to alarm
monitoring services, along with restrictions on all LECs' recording or
use of data from calls to alarm monitoring providers for purposes of
marketing competing alarm monitoring services. Arguments that ancillary
authority based on Section 275 could support rules that prohibit ISPs
that also offer alarm monitoring services from blocking or throttling
alarm monitoring traffic or engaging in anticompetitive paid
prioritization of alarm monitoring traffic are premised on a reading of
Section 275 as a far broader mandate to protecting alarm monitoring
competition than the specifics of its language support. Given the
Commission's existing ability to directly apply the duties and
restrictions of Section 275 to the specific entities covered by that
Section, the record leaves us unable to conclude that the proposed
alarm monitoring-related ISP conduct rules are sufficiently
``necessary'' to our implementation of Section 275 to satisfy the
standard for ancillary authority under Comcast. Nor does the record
demonstrate what basis we have for the proposed exercise of ancillary
authority to regulate any ISPs that fall outside the scope of Section
275 but that offer alarm monitoring services.
270. Authority With Respect to Audio and Video. The Open Internet
Order's theories of authority related to Commission oversight of audio
and video offerings have significant deficiencies, as well. In that
Order, the Commission argued that because local television stations and
radio stations distributed their content over the internet, actions by
ISPs to block, degrade, or charge unreasonable fees for carrying such
traffic would interfere with certain statutory responsibilities. Once
again, the Commission was unclear whether it was asserting direct or
ancillary authority. The Open Internet Order cited policy
pronouncements from provisions of the Act and associated precedent
without any clear indication how the underlying authority directly
applied to ISPs' conduct. To the extent that the Open Internet Order
was claiming ancillary authority, its failure to forthrightly engage
with an ancillary authority theory again leaves it unclear how conduct
rules are sufficiently ``necessary'' to its implementation of these
provisions to satisfy the standard for ancillary authority under
Comcast, nor are these issues adequately addressed by the limited
references to this potential authority in the record.
271. We find significant limitations to the Open Internet Order's
theories based on direct authority under Title VI of the Act, as well.
The Commission contended in the Open Internet Order that ``MVPD
practices that discriminatorily impede'' competing online video are a
``related practice'' to video program carriage agreements and thus
subject to the restrictions in Section 616(a) of the Act. That
expansive view of a ``related practice'' seems challenging to square
with the overall structure and approach of Section 616, which is
focused on facilitating program carriage agreements between video
programming vendors and MVPDs. But the Open Internet Order suggests
that an MVPD/ISP could violate rules implementing Section 616(a) with
respect to the programming of a video programming vendor that never
even sought a program carriage agreement with that MVPD. In such cases,
there appears to be no actual or potential program carriage agreement
to which the MVPD/ISP's conduct would be a ``related practice[ ].'' To
the contrary, the broader structure of Section 616(a) seems to
contemplate that there would be some effort by the video programming
vendor to obtain carriage, subject to the possibly of a complaint.
Neither the Open Internet Order nor the record here provides a response
enabling us to address these concerns.
272. The Open Internet Order's legal theory under Section 628 of
the Act also appears to have substantial shortcomings. The Open
Internet Order contended that ``[a] cable or telephone company's
interference with online transmission of programming by DBS operators
or stand-alone online video programming aggregators that may function
as competitive alternatives to traditional MVPDs would frustrate
Congress's stated goals in enacting Section 628 of the Act'' and
``[t]he Commission therefore is authorized to adopt open internet rules
under Section 628(b), (c)(1), and (j).'' Under the terms of the
statute, that at most could restrict
[[Page 7907]]
such entities' conduct if it constitutes ``unfair or deceptive acts or
practices the purpose or effect of which is to prevent or hinder
significantly the ability of an MVPD to deliver satellite cable
programming or satellite broadcast programming.'' The cursory
discussion in the Open Internet Order, while suggesting that ISP
practices could have some effect on the viability of stand-alone MVPDs
like DISH, does not provide any meaningful explanation why particular
conduct would rise to the level of ``prevent[ing] or significantly
hinder[ing]'' DISH (or others) from being able to deliver satellite
cable programming or satellite broadcast programming. The minimal
discussion of this Title VI authority in the record here does not
remedy that shortcoming either.
273. Authority With Respect to Wireless Licensees. Although the
Commission could rely on Title III licensing authority to support
conduct rules as it has in the past, that historical approach would
result in disparate treatment of ISPs, enabling conduct rules
encompassing wireless ISPs, but not wireline ISPs. For the reasons set
forth below, we decline to adopt a patchwork of rules that subjects
different categories of ISPs to different treatment. In addition,
applying conduct rules just to such providers would have the anomalous
result of more heavily regulating providers that face among the most
competitive marketplace conditions.
d. Our Evaluation of Possible Authority for Conduct Rules Confirms That
Such Rules Are Inappropriate
274. Our analyses of potential theories of legal authority for
conduct rules (other than Title II authority relied upon in the Title
II Order) persuades us on the record here that ISP conduct rules are
unwarranted. The two provisions most directly on point--Section 706 of
the 1996 Act and Section 230(b) of the Communications Act--are better
read as policy pronouncements rather than grants of regulatory
authority. In addition, Section 230(b)(2) identifies Congress'
deregulatory policy for the internet, explaining that ``[i]t is the
policy of the United States . . . to preserve the vibrant and
competitive free market that presently exists for the internet and
other interactive computer services, unfettered by Federal or State
regulation.'' This policy is reinforced by the deregulatory objectives
of the 1996 Act more generally. Against that policy backdrop, had
Congress wanted us to regulate ISPs' conduct we find it most likely
that they would have spoken to that directly. Thus, the fact that the
Commission would be left here to comb through myriad provisions of the
Act in an effort to cobble together authority for ISP conduct rules
itself leaves us dubious such rules really are within the authority
granted by Congress. Because we decline to adopt conduct rules here, we
need not reach the arguments in the record that imposing such rules on
ISPs would violate the First Amendment. We are unpersuaded by the
suggestion that allowing ISPs to enter paid prioritization
arrangements, even if subject to a commercial reasonableness standard,
would trigger First Amendment scrutiny as a restriction on entities
wishing to transmit speech on the internet. The failure to restrict
ISPs' actions through conduct rules does not require ISPs to act in any
particular manner, and those arguments do not reveal why allowing ISPs
to decide whether and when to enter paid prioritization arrangements
would constitute state action triggering the First Amendment.
275. In addition, the absence of demonstrated statutory authority
that could support comprehensive conduct rules would leave us with, at
most, a patchwork of non-uniform rules that would have problematic
consequences and doubtful value. Virtually all of the remaining sources
of possible authority identified in the Open Internet Order or the
record here would encompass only discrete subsets of ISPs, such as ISPs
that otherwise are providing common carrier voice services; ISPs that
otherwise are cable operators or MVPDs; or ISPs that hold wireless
licenses, among others. Individually, each of these sources of
authority would leave substantial segments of ISPs unaddressed by any
conduct rules. In addition, most of the remaining sources of authority
would, at most, enable the Commission to target narrow types of
behaviors, including, among other examples, actions by ISPs that
otherwise offer common carrier voice services to interfere with
competing over-the-top voice services or actions by certain ISPs that
otherwise are video providers that harm the distribution of satellite
programming. Importantly, substantial questions also remain on the
record here about the merits of most of those theories of legal
authority. For example, most if not all wired ISPs would appear to fall
outside the scope of any sound basis of authority for conduct rules
addressing the theories of harm identified in the Open Internet Order.
This would leave substantial portions of the marketplace unaddressed by
conduct rules including a number of the largest ISPs.
276. Imposing conduct rules on only some, but not all, ISPs risks
introducing regulation-based market distortions by limiting some ISPs'
ability to participate in the marketplace in a manner equivalent to
other ISPs. ISPs subject to conduct rules would be limited in the ways
in which they could manage traffic on their networks and/or the
commercial arrangements they could enter related to their carriage of
traffic beyond the requirements to which other ISPs are subject. As a
result, they are likely to face increased network costs and network
management challenges and see decreased revenue opportunities from
commercial arrangements relative to existing or potential competitors
not similarly constrained by conduct rules. In various contexts, the
Commission previously has recognized that such artificial regulatory
distinctions can distort the marketplace and undercut competition. The
primary objectives of the 1996 Act are ``[t]o promote competition and
reduce regulation,'' and the Commission likewise has observed that
``[c]ompetitive markets are superior mechanisms for protecting
consumers by ensuring that goods and services are provided to consumers
in the most efficient manner possible and at prices that reflect the
cost of production.'' Thus, the risk that disparate regulatory
treatment under patchwork conduct rules could harm existing or
potential competition is a significant concern. Even assuming arguendo
that the record demonstrated harms for which conduct rules were
warranted--which it does not--the record does not demonstrate that any
incremental benefits from patchwork regulation would outweigh the harm
from the resulting potential for marketplace distortions.
277. Patchwork conduct rules also would not appear to address many
of the theories of harm identified in the Open Internet Order. A number
of those theories of harm would need to be addressed by comprehensive
or near-comprehensive conduct rules. Here, by contrast, substantial
segments of the marketplace would be left unaddressed by patchwork ISP
conduct rules. Thus, patchwork conduct rules that conceivably might be
supported by authority identified here would not meaningfully address
such concerns, even assuming arguendo that the record here supported
such theories of harm.
C. Enforcement
278. In light of the modifications to our regulations, we also
revise our enforcement practices under them. The Internet Freedom NPRM
sought comment on the Commission's
[[Page 7908]]
Ombudsperson, formal complaint rules, and advisory opinions established
in the Title II Order. For the reasons discussed below, we remove these
enforcement mechanisms. Our existing informal complaint procedures
combined with transparency and competition, as well as antitrust and
consumer protection laws, will ensure that ISPs continue to be held
accountable for their actions, while removing unnecessary and
ineffective regulatory processes and unused mechanisms.
279. Open Internet Ombudsperson. We find that there is no need for
a separate Ombudsperson and thereby eliminate the Ombudsperson
position. The Title II Order created the role of an Ombudsperson ``to
provide assistance to individuals and organizations with questions or
complaints regarding the open internet to ensure that small and often
unrepresented groups reach the appropriate bureaus and offices to
address specific issues.'' In particular, the Title II Order tasked the
Ombudsperson with ``conducting trend analysis of open internet
complaints and, more broadly, market conditions, that could be
summarized in reports to the Commission regarding how the market is
functioning for various stakeholders . . . . [and] investigat[ing] and
bring[ing] attention to open internet concerns, and refer[ing] matters
to the Enforcement Bureau for potential further investigation.'' We
agree that it is important for the Commission to have staff who monitor
consumer complaints and provide consumers with additional information;
however, we disagree that a separate Ombudsperson role is necessary to
perform this function specifically for transparency complaints.
Instead, as suggested in the record, we determine that the existing
consumer complaint process administered by the Commission's Consumer
and Governmental Affairs Bureau is best suited to and will process all
informal transparency complaints. We reject as unsupported any
suggestions that only an Ombudsperson, and not other professional staff
from the Consumer and Governmental Affairs Bureau, would be able to
engage with consumers in beneficial ways. Indeed, the name, purpose,
and well-established track record for that Bureau make clear its
understanding of and responsiveness to consumer concerns.
280. We find that staff from the Consumer and Governmental Affairs
Bureau--other than the Ombudsperson--have been performing the
Ombudsperson functions envisioned by the Title II Order. Since the
existing rules became effective in June 2015, the Consumer and
Governmental Affairs Bureau has engaged in an ongoing review of
informal consumer complaints submitted to the Ombudsperson and to the
Commission's Consumer Complaint Center. Many complaints convey
frustration or dissatisfaction with a person or entity or discuss a
subject without actually alleging wrongdoing on which the Commission
may act; others represent isolated incidents that do not form a trend
that allow judicious use of our limited resources. Staff from the
Consumer and Governmental Affairs Bureau review all informal open
internet complaints received by the Commission, and work with staff in
the Enforcement Bureau who also monitor media reports and conduct
additional research to identify complaint trends so the Commission can
best target its enforcement capabilities toward entities that have a
pattern of violating the Communications Act and the Commission's rules,
regulations, and orders. The Commission's decision not to expend its
limited resources investigating each complaint that consumers believe
may be related to the open internet rules does not mean that the
Commission ``has not taken the time to analyze these materials'' as
alleged by some parties in the record. Rather, this ongoing review has
helped identify trends in this subject matter as well as the many
others over which we have jurisdiction and which generate far more
consumer complaints.
281. We emphasize that we are not making any changes to our
informal complaint processes. Our decision to eliminate the Open
Internet Ombudsperson does not impact the existing review of trends or
existing responses to consumer complaints by the Consumer and
Governmental Affairs Bureau and the Enforcement Bureau. Instead, it
reduces confusion by making clear that staff specifically trained to
work with consumers, known as Consumer Advocacy and Mediation
Specialists (CAMS), are best suited to help consumers by providing them
with understandable information about the issue they might be
experiencing and to help file a complaint against a service provider if
the consumer believes the service provider is violating our rules. When
a consumer needs additional information that the CAMS cannot provide,
that complaint is often shared with the expert Bureau or Office to
provide additional information to the consumer.
282. Our experience also persuades us that the demand for a
distinct Ombudsperson is not sufficient to retain the position. For the
10 month period from December 16, 2016 through November 16, 2017, the
email address and phone number associated with the Ombudsperson
received only 38 emails and 10 calls related to the open internet--with
only 7 emails and 2 calls coming in during the 5 month period between
mid-July and mid November 2017. By comparison, during that same time
period, the Consumer and Governmental Affairs Bureau's Consumer
Complaint Center received roughly 7,700 complaints that consumers
identified as relating to open internet. This figure includes
complaints filed through the Consumer Complaint Center and the FCC Call
Center for which the consumer self-selected the issue ``Open Internet/
Net Neutrality'' or the call center agent selected ``Open Internet''
based on the consumer's description of the issue, and does not exclude
open internet campaigns. These statistics make clear that consumers
have generally not been seeking out the Ombudsperson position for
assistance with concerns about internet openness and that consumers are
comfortable working with the Consumer and Governmental Affairs Bureau
to protect their interests.
283. Formal Complaint Rules. We similarly find that it is no longer
necessary to allow for formal complaints under Part 8 of the Act as we
believe that the informal complaint process is sufficient in this area.
We encourage consumers to file informal complaints for apparent
violations of the transparency rule in order to assist the Commission
in monitoring the broadband market and furthering our goals under
Section 257 to identify market entry barriers. We also note that under
the revised regulatory approach adopted today, consumers and other
entities potentially impacted by ISPs' conduct will have other remedies
available to them outside of the Commission under other consumer
protection laws to enforce the promises made under the transparency
rule.
284. Advisory Opinions. Because we are eliminating the conduct
rules, we find that the justification for enforcement advisory opinions
no longer exists. Moreover, our experience with enforcement advisory
opinions and the evidence in the record would lead us to eliminate the
use of advisory opinions in the context of open internet conduct in any
event. The record indicates that enforcement advisory opinions do not
diminish regulatory uncertainty, particularly for small providers.
Rather they add costs and uncertain timelines since there is no
specific timeframe within which to act, which can also inhibit
innovation. Further, the fact that no ISP has requested an advisory
opinion since
[[Page 7909]]
they first became available further demonstrates that they are not
needed.
III. Cost-Benefit Analysis
285. The Internet Freedom NPRM solicited input for a cost-benefit
analysis in this proceeding, with special emphasis on identifying
``whether the decision will have positive net benefits.'' There was
generally favorable record support for conducting this analysis.
Relying on the findings discussed above in light of the record before
us and as a result of our economic analysis, we use a cost-benefit
analysis framework to evaluate key decisions. While the record provides
little data that would allow us to quantify the magnitudes of many of
the effects, our findings with respect to the key decisions we make in
this Order allow for a reasonable assessment of the direction of the
effect on economic efficiency (i.e. net positive or net negative
benefits). This assessment is equivalent to conducting a qualitative
cost-benefit analysis, because the purpose of comparing benefits and
costs is to identify whether a policy change improves economic
efficiency. We reject the argument that the Internet Freedom NPRM
provided inadequate notice regarding our cost-benefit analysis here.
The Commission made clear in that NPRM that it ``propose[d] to compare
the costs and the benefits'' of each of the ``changes for which we seek
comment above.'' It also provided detailed guidance to commenting
parties about the way in which the Commission proposed to conduct its
cost-benefit analysis, and the nature of the information it was seeking
in order to do so. The result is a robust record on we have based our
analysis. Moreover, that NPRM plainly provided ``the terms or substance
of the proposed rule,'' and also provided ``sufficient factual detail
and rationale for the rule to permit interested parties to comment
meaningfully.'' Nor can there be any question that ``[t]he final rule''
is a ``logical outgrowth'' of the notice.
286. As proposed in the Internet Freedom NPRM, we evaluate
maintaining the classification of broadband internet access service as
a telecommunications service (i.e., Title II regulation); maintaining
the internet conduct rule; maintaining the no-blocking rule;
maintaining the no-throttling rule; and maintaining the ban on paid
prioritization. Throughout this section, when discussing maintaining
broadband internet access service as a telecommunications service, we
mean as implemented by the Title II Order, where the Commission forbore
from applying some sections of the Act and some Commission rules. We
also evaluate the benefits and costs associated with transparency
regulations. We make each of these evaluations by organizing the
relevant economic findings made throughout the Order into a cost-
benefit framework.
287. The primary benefits, costs, and transfers attributable to
this Order are the changes in the economic welfare of consumers, ISPs,
and edge providers that would occur due to our actions. In our analysis
of the net benefits of maintaining the Title II classification, the
internet conduct rule, and the bright-line rules, we compare against a
state we would expect to exist if we did not maintain the
classification or a particular rule. As explained in the Internet
Freedom NPRM, we ``recognize that in certain cases repealing or
eliminating a rule does not result in a total lack of regulation but
instead means that other regulations continue to operate or other
regulatory bodies will have authority.'' As discussed elsewhere in this
Order, when analyzing the net benefits of maintaining the Title II
classification, our comparison is to a situation where a Title I regime
for broadband internet access service, and antitrust and consumer
protection enforcement, remain in place. Further, given this Order's
adoption of a transparency rule, when considering net benefits of the
current rules we compare against a state where the transparency rule we
adopt is in effect (as well as the antitrust and consumer protection
enforcement that exists under a Title I classification). We also
recognize that the actions we analyze separately could potentially be
interdependent, but we believe a separate consideration of each is a
reasonable way to approximate the net benefits. We believe that
attempting to assert the nature of these interdependencies,
particularly given the limited record on such matters, would introduce
considerable subjectivity while not likely improving the ability of the
analysis to guide our decisions. Moreover, we consider additional
regulation, for example, adding an additional rule to a baseline
package of Title II regulation and another rule (or none) is likely to
have greater negative impacts in terms of regulatory uncertainty, and
distortion of efficient choices, than the baseline package, while at
best having little or no additional impact on the positive impacts (if
any) of each element of the baseline package. That is, the interactions
increase uncertainty and the unintended side effects of each element,
without making each element materially more effective.
288. To conduct the cost-benefit analysis, we first consider the
question of maintaining the Title II classification of broadband
internet access service. We next consider approaches to transparency.
Then to evaluate the internet conduct rule and the bright-line rules,
we assume that we will not maintain the Title II classification and we
will adopt our transparency rule. This approach allows us practically
to evaluate the rules in a way that incorporates the decisions on
classification and transparency that we have come to in this Order.
289. Maintaining Title II Classification of Broadband Internet
Access Service. We have found that the Title II Order decreased
investment and is likely to continue to decrease investment by ISPs.
These decreases in investments are likely to result in less deployment
of service to unserved areas and less upgrading of facilities in
already served areas. For consumers, this means some will likely not
have access to high-speed services over fixed or mobile networks and
some will not experience better service as quickly as they otherwise
would under a Title I classification. While the evidence in the record
on the effect of Title II is varied in terms of details due to
different methodologies, data, etc., we found that the Title II
classification did directionally decrease investment by ISPs. Since the
Title II Order classified broadband internet access service under Title
II and adopted rules simultaneously, it is difficult methodologically
to make a clear delineation between the effect of the classification
and the rules. However, the theoretical underpinnings of our finding
about the effect of Title II specifically also support the finding of a
negative impact on investment as a result of Title II per se.
290. As the Internet Freedom NPRM noted, ``the networks built with
capital investments are only a means to an end . . . the private costs
borne by consumers and businesses of maintaining the status quo [i.e.,
Title II classification] result from decreased value derived from using
the networks.'' Ideally, we would estimate consumers' and businesses'
valuations of the service or service improvements foregone caused by
Title II classification. Unfortunately, the record before us does not
allow for such estimation. We can reasonably conclude, however, that
providers expect to recoup their investments over time through revenues
generated by employing the networks resulting from the investment.
Since these revenues come from consumers and businesses who are willing
to pay
[[Page 7910]]
at least their value of the service, the investment foregone due to
Title II is a lower bound on the value consumers lose if the FCC
maintains the Title II classification. This is a conservative estimate
as the social welfare impact of this forgone investment would likely
have been positive, because frequently (1) a customer's willingness to
pay exceeds what the customer actually pays, and (2) the provider may
make an economic profit. We therefore conclude that the private costs
of maintaining a Title II classification due to foregone network
investment are directionally negative and likely constitute at least
several billion dollars annually based on the record.
291. The Commission also asked in the Internet Freedom NPRM about
additional costs that could result from foregone network investments.
When regulation discourages investment in the network, society is
likely to lose some spillover benefits that the purchasers of broadband
internet access do not themselves capture. Such forgone benefits can
include network externalities (the network becomes more valuable the
more users are on the network, but individual ISPs do not capture all
of these, as they are obtained by end users on other ISPs' networks),
and improvements in productivity and innovation that occur because
broadband is a general-purpose technology. The record provides little
information that could be used to quantify such costs, but it is
reasonable to conclude that there are social costs beyond the private
costs associated with the foregone investment.
292. Next, we consider the benefits associated with maintaining the
Title II classification. The relevant comparison is what incremental
benefit the Title II classification provides over and above the Title I
scenario. In the Title I scenario, the FTC has jurisdiction over
broadband internet access service providers. The record does not
convince us that Title II classification per se provides any benefit
over and above Title I classification. We also find above that the
record does not provide evidence supporting the conclusion that the
Title II classification affects edge investment. To the extent Title II
provides a benefit, it appears to do so by serving as a legal basis
relied upon to adopt rules. Therefore, in this cost-benefit analysis we
conclude the incremental benefits of maintaining the Title II
classification are approximately zero.
293. Finding that the benefits of maintaining the Title II
classification are approximately zero, coupled with our finding that
the private and social costs are positive, we conclude that maintaining
the Title II classification would have net negative benefits. Thus,
maintaining the Title II classification would decrease overall economic
welfare, and our cost-benefit analysis supports the decision to
reclassify broadband internet access service as a Title I service.
294. Evaluating Transparency Rules. As discussed already, we find
that the benefits of a transparency rule are positive based on the
record. Given our decision to classify broadband internet access
service under Title I, the benefits of a transparency rule are expected
to be of considerable magnitude since it is a key element of our
approach of relying on enforcement under antitrust and consumer
protection law to prevent and remedy harmful behaviors by ISPs.
Numerous commenters indicate the benefits of a free and open internet
are large, so to the extent a transparency rule under our Title I
approach is important for maintaining a free and open internet, we can
conclude the benefits are positive and considerable. Furthermore,
transparency can provide other benefits in terms of consumer welfare.
Namely, if transparency helps mitigate economic deadweight loss due to
information asymmetry or if it helps consumers better satisfy their
preferences in their purchasing decisions, then additional benefits
will accrue. We therefore conclude that our transparency approach, as
well as the transparency approaches in the Open Internet Order and the
Title II Order, all have positive benefits.
295. The costs of the transparency rules may vary given differences
in their implementation. Comparing the transparency approach in the
Open Internet Order and the Title II Order, we conclude the costs were
greater for the latter. Based on the record, we determined above that
the additional transparency requirements in the Title II Order were
particularly burdensome. Although the record is limited on the costs of
these transparency rules, the Commission's Paperwork Reduction Act
(PRA) filings indicate the Title II Order transparency rule increased
the burden on the public by thousands of hours per year, costing
hundreds of thousands of dollars. While we do not have specific
information on our transparency rule's costs, it is fairly similar to
that in the Open Internet Order. Therefore, we conclude that a
reasonable approximation for the PRA burden associated with our rule is
approximately half the preceding burden estimate. We recognize there
are other costs to this requirement not accounted for in the PRA
estimate, though the PRA estimate provides a starting point for sizing
the costs, particularly as we compare several alternative transparency
approaches.
296. Combining our conclusion about the benefits of a transparency
rule with our assessments of the costs of the several transparency
rules, we conclude that the transparency rule in the Title II Order
would have the smallest net positive benefit of the three. That is
because we do not believe the additional elements of the Title II Order
transparency regime have significant additional benefits but they do
impose significant additional costs. However, our transparency rule
would have a larger net positive benefit than the transparency rule in
the Title II Order. Therefore, our cost-benefit analysis of the
transparency alternatives supports our decision to adopt a transparency
rule more limited than the one in the Title II Order.
297. Maintaining the Internet Conduct Rule. We have determined
elsewhere that the internet conduct rule has created uncertainty and
ultimately deterred innovation and investment. The record does not
provide sufficient information for us to estimate the magnitude of this
effect. However, we do find that maintaining the internet conduct rule
imposes social costs in terms of increased uncertainty, reduced
investment, and reduced innovation.
298. We also find above that the benefits of the internet conduct
standard are limited if not approximately zero. In this cost-benefit
analysis, we consider the incremental benefit of the internet conduct
standard relative to the regulatory environment created by this Order.
The regulatory environment created by this Order will have antitrust
and consumer protection enforcement in place through the FTC. We find
that the internet conduct standard provides approximately zero
additional benefits compared to that baseline.
299. Based on the record available, we conclude that maintaining
the internet conduct standard would impose net negative benefits. The
costs of the rule are considerable as the evidence shows that it had
large effects on consumers obtaining innovative services (as
demonstrated by the zero-rating experiences). The innovations that were
delayed or never brought to market would likely have cost many millions
or even billions of dollars in lost consumer welfare. At the same time,
for the reasons explained already, the benefits of the conduct rule are
approximately zero. This leads us to conclude that the internet conduct
standard has a net negative effect on economic welfare,
[[Page 7911]]
and supports our decision not to maintain the internet conduct rule.
300. Maintaining the Ban on Paid Prioritization. We have determined
elsewhere in this Order that the ban on paid prioritization has created
uncertainty and reduced ISP investment. We also find that the ban is
likely to prevent certain types of innovative applications from being
developed or adopted. The record does not provide sufficient
information for us to estimate the magnitude of these effects. However,
we do find that maintaining the ban on paid prioritization imposes
substantial social costs.
301. We also find above that the benefits of the ban on paid
prioritization are limited. In this cost-benefit analysis, we consider
the incremental benefit of the ban on paid prioritization relative to
the regulatory environment created by this Order. The regulatory
environment created by this Order will have antitrust and consumer
protection enforcement in place. So we must ask what the ban on paid
prioritization provides in additional benefits when compared to that
baseline. We concluded that transparency combined with antitrust and
consumer enforcement at the FTC will be able to address the vast
majority of harms the ban on paid prioritization is intended to
prevent. To the extent there are harms not well addressed by this
enforcement, we would expect those cases to be infrequent and involve
relatively small amounts of harm, though the record does not allow us
to estimate this magnitude. Antitrust law, in combination with the
transparency rule we adopt, is particularly well-suited to addressing
any potential or actual anticompetitive harms that may arise from paid
prioritization arrangements. While antitrust law does not address harms
that may arise from the legal use of market power, we have found that
such market power is limited, and ISPs also have countervailing
incentives to keep edge provider output high and keep subscribers on
the network. The record therefore supports a finding of small to zero
benefits.
302. Based on the record available, we conclude that maintaining
the ban on paid prioritization would impose net negative benefits. The
record shows that in some cases innovative services and business models
would benefit from paid prioritization. At the same time, for the
reasons explained already, the benefits of maintaining the ban are
small or zero. We therefore conclude that the ban on paid
prioritization has a net negative effect on economic welfare. This
conclusion supports our decision to not maintain the ban on paid
prioritization.
303. Maintaining the Bans on Blocking and Throttling. We find that
the costs of these bans are likely small. This is supported by the fact
that ISPs voluntarily have chosen in some cases to commit to not
blocking or throttling. However, we also recognize that these rules may
create some compliance costs nonetheless. For example, when considering
new approaches to managing network traffic, an ISP must apply due
diligence in evaluating whether the practice might be perceived as
running afoul of the rules. As network management becomes increasingly
complex, the compliance costs of these rules could increase.
304. Having adopted a transparency rule, we find the benefits of
bans on blocking and throttling are approximately zero since the
transparency rule will allow antitrust and consumer protection law,
coupled with consumer expectations and ISP incentives, to mitigate
potential harms. That is, we have determined that replacing the
prohibitions on blocking and throttling with a transparency rule
implements a lower-cost method of ensuring that threats to internet
openness are exposed and deterred by market forces, public opprobrium,
and enforcement of the consumer protection laws. We conclude therefore
that maintaining the bans on blocking and throttling has a small net
negative benefit, compared to the new regulatory environment we create
(i.e. Title I classification and our transparency rule).
IV. Order
A. Denial of INCOMPAS Petition To Modify Protective Orders
305. INCOMPAS requests that we modify the protective orders in four
recent major transaction proceedings involving internet service
providers to allow confidential materials submitted in those dockets to
be used in this proceeding. INCOMPAS argues that the materials ``are
necessary to understanding and fully analyzing incumbent broadband
providers' ability and incentives to harm edge providers.'' The motion
is opposed by the three companies whose materials would be most
affected--Comcast, Charter and AT&T--as well as by Verizon. For the
reasons set forth below, after carefully ``balancing . . . the public
and private interests involved,'' we deny INCOMPAS's request.
306. The Commission's protective orders limit parties' use of the
materials obtained under the protective order solely to ``the
preparation and conduct'' of that particular proceeding, and expressly
prohibit the materials being used ``for any other purpose, including .
. . in any other administrative, regulatory or judicial proceedings.''
The terms of the relevant protective orders therefore prohibit INCOMPAS
from using the confidential materials it obtained in those prior
dockets in the current proceeding. Further, parties reasonably expect
that the information they submit pursuant to the strictures of a
protective order will be used in accordance with the terms of that
order and that the order's explicit prohibitions will not be changed
years later. That is not to imply, however, that the Commission cannot
request the submission of information in a proceeding simply because it
has been provided pursuant to a protective order in another proceeding.
307. Before discussing the substance of INCOMPAS's request, we note
that, as a formal matter, the Commission does not modify protective
orders to allow materials to be used in a different proceeding. Rather,
where we find that the public interest is served by submitting certain
materials into a docket, we do so, subject to a protective order
specific to that proceeding if the material is confidential. That is
true whether the materials have been submitted in prior proceedings or
not. The question before us, then, is whether we will require the
relevant parties to submit into this docket the presumptively
confidential information INCOMPAS has identified.
308. The Commission is not required to enter into the record and
review every document that a party to a proceeding deems relevant,
especially where, as here, those documents may number in the tens of
thousands. Nor, as a general matter, does the Commission allow for
discovery by parties--which is essentially what INCOMPAS seeks here--
except in adjudications that have been set for hearing. The Commission
has broad discretion in how to manage its own proceedings, and we find
several problems with requiring the materials INCOMPAS seeks to be
submitted into this rulemaking docket.
309. First, much of the material INCOMPAS seeks is now several
years old and INCOMPAS has offered little demonstration of its
relevance to this proceeding. For example, Comcast's ability to
discriminate against online video providers in 2009 and 2010 shines
little light on its ability to do so now. Also, as the opponents argue,
many of the confidential materials cited by the Commission in its prior
transaction
[[Page 7912]]
decisions were cited as part of a larger group of mostly publicly
available information. Having the competitively sensitive information
from those transactions in this record would therefore not
significantly add to the Commission's understanding of the issues,
especially since the participants in the current proceeding and the
Commission already have available the Commission's prior conclusions
and reasoning, as well as the underlying public information.
310. Second, INCOMPAS asks for information only from the few
industry participants who happen to have had large transactions before
the Commission. But where the Commission has sought information in
large rulemaking proceedings, it sought information from the entire
industry, not just from a select few participants. Transaction review
is an adjudicatory matter, involving the entities engaging in the
transaction--not the entire industry or marketplace. Particularly given
that there are thousands of ISPs doing business in the United States,
INCOMPAS does not address how a quite incomplete picture of industry
practices could meaningfully improve the Commission's analysis.
311. Third, granting the request would pose several administrative
difficulties. It is unclear how much of the material INCOMPAS seeks is
still in the possession of the parties: The relevant portions of the
proceedings are finished, and many of the materials may have been
destroyed. And what is available at the Commission would be difficult
and costly to produce. Making the information available to others also
would be administratively difficult. For example, in the recent
Business Data Services proceeding, the Commission made the
competitively sensitive data available for review only through a secure
data enclave, a process which took significant time and resources to
establish. And in most Commission proceedings, the parties who own the
confidential information are required to provide that material directly
to persons who seek to review it pursuant to terms outlined in the
applicable protective order. Here, in contrast, it is likely that the
Commission itself would have to make the confidential information
available, further depleting scarce Commission resources.
312. Finally, as noted above, the materials INCOMPAS seeks were
provided pursuant to express assurances against their use in future
proceedings.
313. INCOMPAS cites two examples in which the Commission staff
placed into the record competitively sensitive materials originally
submitted in another docket. We find both inapposite. As an initial
matter, we note that the Commission is not bound by its staff's prior
decisions. The first example INCOMPAS cites involved a series of
spectrum license transfers between wireless telecommunications
companies where the Commission added confidential data to the docket
under a new protective order. When evaluating transactions such as
these, the Commission regularly uses subscriber data derived from
regular periodic confidential filings made by all telecommunications
companies to determine market shares. In such transactions, this use of
subscriber data is often the only way to calculate market share, which
is a critical element to analyzing the potential competitive harms of
the proposed transaction. Balancing that need against the potential
competitive harm to providers, we have determined that allowing that
material to be reviewed pursuant to a protective order best serves the
public interest. For the reasons expressed above, we do not reach the
same conclusions with respect to the materials here.
314. INCOMPAS also cites the recent investigation of certain
business data services tariffs, in which the Commission placed the
record of the contemporaneous business data services rulemaking
proceeding into the docket of the tariff investigations. As the
opponents note, the tariff investigation was not only related to the
rulemaking proceeding, it actually was determined by the staff to be
``an outgrowth'' of that proceeding. Further, there was no Commission
decision in the rulemaking proceeding on which the participants in the
tariff proceeding could rely; the proceeding was still ongoing. All of
the participants in the tariff proceeding, moreover, were participating
in the rulemaking proceeding. Here, by contrast, the current rulemaking
is not related to the prior transactions; the parties may rely on prior
written Commission decisions; and literally millions more comments have
been submitted in this rulemaking than in the prior transaction
proceedings. Finally, we note that none of the parties that owned the
confidential information in the Business Data Services rulemaking
proceeding raised confidentiality concerns with respect to that
information being placed into the tariff investigation docket. Here,
they do.
315. Even absent the legal and administrative barriers discussed
above, the substance of the past transaction orders compels us to deny
INCOMPAS' motion. When, as it has in the past, the Commission
determines a specific transaction involving certain large broadband
providers is likely to create competitive or other public interest
harm, the conditions imposed are applicable only to those entities
engaging in the transaction. Those proceedings involved some of the
nation's largest broadband providers, and the Commission's conclusions
were based on the specific circumstances involved. This is because
transaction review is an adjudicatory matter, involving the motives,
plans, and capabilities of the entities engaging in the transaction--
not the entire industry or marketplace. Indeed, transaction reviews
specifically do not address issues that are not transaction-specific
but are industry-wide. The targeted and flexible approach the
Commission used to ameliorate the potential harms it found in those
transactions is not transferable to a permanent, one-size-fits-all
approach in this rulemaking applicable to hundreds of ISPs.
316. Further, in those limited instances in which the Commission
found conduct remedies necessary, it almost always applied them on a
temporary basis, in recognition that markets change over time. That is
true even more so in industries that are characterized by rapidly
changing technologies. Similarly, the Commission often has provided
that it will ``consider a petition for modification of this condition
if it can be demonstrated that there has been a material change in
circumstance or the condition has proven unduly burdensome, rendering
the condition no longer necessary in the public interest,'' and has
acted accordingly. None of this would be the case with respect to the
regulations that some commenters urge us to adopt in this rulemaking.
317. INCOMPAS argues that ``[l]ooking to the past is the standard
way for administrative agencies to make predictive judgments.''
However, the analysis supporting our decision to re-classify broadband
internet access service as an information service is quite different
from the analysis the Commission employs when conducting a transaction
review. In this rulemaking, we are not considering whether, as a result
of a transfer of a Commission license, a licensee is likely to gain
market power, allowing it to take anticompetitive actions that it
otherwise could not. Instead, we are reasonably considering the long-
term costs and benefits of Title II and other ex ante regulation in an
increasingly dynamic market. As such, we choose a conservative and
administrable approach to formulating a light-touch
[[Page 7913]]
regulatory framework--which is appropriate in a rulemaking.
318. In addition to rejecting the INCOMPAS petition on the merits,
we find that the petition is procedurally flawed. Although some of the
companies that objected to INCOMPAS's request were the applicants in
the proceedings from which INCOMPAS seeks confidential information,
they are not the only owners of confidential information submitted in
those dockets. INCOMPAS did not file its request in those dockets--
which are long dormant--and others whose confidential information would
be disclosed if we were to grant INCOMPAS's request have not been
notified of the request to have the opportunity to object. That would
need to occur before any of their information could be made available,
even pursuant to a protective order.
319. Taking into account and sensibly balancing the factors
discussed above, we find that the public interest would not be served
by requiring the submission into the docket of the current proceeding
the presumptively confidential information INCOMPAS seeks. We therefore
deny INCOMPAS's request.
B. Denial of NHMC Motion Regarding Informal Consumer Complaints
320. The National Hispanic Media Coalition (NHMC) requests that we
incorporate in the record of this proceeding the informal complaint
materials released as part of NHMC's Freedom of Information Act (FOIA)
request and establish a new pleading cycle for public comment on those
materials. NHMC argues that the materials ``are directly relevant to
the [NPRM's] questions regarding the effectiveness of the [Title II
Order]'' and that if we deny NHMC's request, ``any decision in this
proceeding would be based on an insufficient and fundamentally flawed
record.'' The motion is opposed by several parties who argue that the
informal complaint materials are not relevant to this proceeding, and
that the motion ``appears to be . . . aimed [ ] at prolonging this
proceeding unnecessarily.'' For the reasons set forth below, we deny
NHMC's request.
321. In responding to NHMC's underlying FOIA requests, we produced
nearly 70,000 pages of records responsive to the requests. The
documents we provided to NHMC included informal consumer complaints
filed with the Consumer and Governmental Affairs Bureau, data relating
to the complaints, responses to the informal complaints from the
carrier involved in a specific complaint--all filed by the consumer
under the category of Open Internet/Net Neutrality--and consumer
complaint correspondence with the Open Internet Ombudsperson. We
provided this large quantity of documents to NHMC on a rolling basis
and made all of the documents available to the public in our FOIA
Electronic Reading Room.
322. Under Commission rules, and as noted by opponents to the
motion, ``NHMC is free to put into the record whatever it believes to
be relevant via ex parte letters.'' NHMC began receiving the documents
it claims are relevant to the proceeding on June 20, 2017. During the
following months, NHMC engaged with Commission staff to discuss the
consumer complaint documents. NHMC also conducted an Expert Analysis of
the consumer complaint documents and submitted the analysis along with
the complaints it found relevant in the record, in addition to
submitting the full universe of consumer complaints it received under
the FOIA request into the record on December 1--nearly three months
after the Commission produced them all. Thus, we remain unpersuaded
that NHMC requires additional time to review the documents and instead
agree with commenters that NHMC has raised ``the mere existence of
these complaints as a pretext for delay.''
323. The Internet Freedom NPRM sought comment on consumer harm in a
variety of contexts and, in response, received over 22 million comments
discussing consumers' view of the Title II Order, including any harm
that may or may not have occurred under its rules. After routinely
reviewing the consumer complaints over the past two years, and
conducting a robust review of the voluminous record in this proceeding,
we agree with opponents to the motion that ``it is exceedingly unlikely
that these informal complaints identify any net neutrality `problem'
that [advocates] have somehow overlooked in their many massive
submissions in this docket.'' The Commission takes consumer complaints
seriously and finds them valuable in informing us about trends in the
marketplace, but we reiterate that they are informal complaints that,
in most instances, have not been verified. Further, the overwhelming
majority of these informal complaints do not allege conduct implicating
the Open Internet rules. Of the complaints that do discuss ISPs, they
often allege frustration with a person or entity, but do not allege
wrongdoing under the Open Internet rules. The consumer complaints NHMC
submitted in the record as part of the Expert Analysis further support
this point. Further, we are not required to resolve all of these
informal complaints before proceeding with a rulemaking. Since we do
not rely on these informal complaints as the basis for the decisions we
make today, we do not have an obligation to incorporate them into the
record.
324. We are convinced that we have a full and complete record on
which to base our determination today without incorporating the
materials requested by NHMC. Further, because the record remained open
for over three months after the complete production of documents under
NHMC FOIA's request, and NHMC filed an analysis the materials it deemed
relevant in the record, we believe that NHMC had ample opportunity to
``meaningfully review the informal complaint materials and provide
comment.''
V. Procedural Matters
A. The Administrative Record
325. In reviewing the record in this rulemaking, the Commission
complied with its obligations under the Administrative Procedure Act
(APA), including the obligation to consider all ``relevant matter''
received, to adequately consider ``important aspect[s] of the
problem,'' and to ``reasonably respond to those comments that raise
significant problems.'' Consistent with these obligations, the
Commission focused its review of the record on the submitted comments
that bear substantively on the legal and public policy consequences of
the actions we take today. Thus, our decision to restore internet
freedom did not rely on comments devoid of substance, or the thousands
of identical or nearly-identical non-substantive comments that simply
convey support or opposition to the proposals in the Internet Freedom
NPRM.
326. Because we have complied with our obligations under the APA,
we reject calls to delay adoption of this Order out of concerns that
certain non-substantive comments (on which the Commission did not rely)
may have been submitted under multiple different names or allegedly
``fake'' names. The Commission is under no legal obligation to adopt
any ``procedural devices'' beyond what the APA requires, such as
identity-verification procedures. In addition, the Commission has
previously decided not to apply its internal rules regarding false
statements in the rulemaking context because we do not want ``to hinder
full and robust public participation in such policymaking proceedings
by encouraging collateral wrangling over
[[Page 7914]]
the truthfulness of the parties' statements.'' To the extent that
members of the public are concerned about the presence in the record of
identical or nearly-identical non-substantive comments that simply
convey support or opposition to the proposals in the Internet Freedom
NPRM, those comments in no way impeded the Commission's ability to
identify or respond to material issues in the record. Indeed, the Order
demonstrates the Commission's deep engagement with the substantive
legal and public policy questions presented in this proceeding.
B. Final Regulatory Flexibility Analysis
327. As required by the Regulatory Flexibility Act (RFA), an
Initial Regulatory Flexibility Analysis (IRFA) was incorporated into
the Internet Freedom NPRM. The Commission sought written public comment
on the possible significant economic impact on small entities regarding
the proposals addressed in the Internet Freedom NPRM, including
comments on the IRFA. Pursuant to the RFA, a Final Regulatory
Flexibility Analysis is set forth in the Order.
C. Paperwork Reduction Act Analysis
328. This document contains new or modified information collection
requirements subject to the Paperwork Reduction Act of 1995 (PRA),
Public Law 104-13. It will be submitted to the Office of Management and
Budget (OMB) for review under Section 3507(d) of the PRA. OMB, the
general public, and other federal agencies will be invited to comment
on the new information collection requirements contained in this
proceeding. In addition, we note that pursuant to the Small Business
Paperwork Relief Act of 2002, Public Law 107-198, see 44 U.S.C.
3506(c)(4), we previously sought specific comment on how the Commission
might further reduce the information collection burden for small
business concerns with fewer than 25 employees.
329. In this present document, we require any person providing
broadband internet access service to publicly disclose accurate
information regarding the network management practices, performance,
and commercial terms of their broadband internet access services
sufficient to enable consumers to make informed choices regarding the
purchase and use of such services and entrepreneurs and other small
businesses to develop, market, and maintain internet offerings. We have
assessed the effects of this rule and find that any burden on small
businesses will be minimal because (1) the rule gives ISPs flexibility
in how to implement the disclosure rule, (2) the rule gives providers
adequate time to develop cost-effective methods of compliance, and (3)
the rule eliminates the additional reporting obligations adopted in the
Title II Order.
D. Congressional Review Act
330. The Commission will send a copy of the Report and Order to
Congress and the Government Accountability Office pursuant to the
Congressional Review Act, see 5 U.S.C. 801(a)(1)(A).
E. Data Quality Act
331. The Commission certifies that it has complied with the Office
of Management and Budget Final Information Quality Bulletin for Peer
Review, 70 FR 2664, January 14, 2005, and the Data Quality Act, Public
Law 106-554 (2001), codified at 44 U.S.C. 3516 note, with regard to its
reliance on influential scientific information in the Declaratory
Ruling, Report and Order, and Order in WC Docket No. 17-108.
F. Accessible Formats
332. To request materials in accessible formats for people with
disabilities (braille, large print, electronic files, audio format),
send an email to fcc.gov">[email protected]fcc.gov or call the Consumer & Governmental
Affairs Bureau at 202-418-0530 (voice), 202-418-0432 (tty). Contact the
FCC to request reasonable accommodations for filing comments
(accessible format documents, sign language interpreters, CARTS, etc.)
by email: [email protected]fcc.gov; phone: (202) 418-0530 (voice), (202) 418-0432
(TTY).
VI. Final Regulatory Flexibility Analysis
333. As required by the Regulatory Flexibility Act of 1980 (RFA),
as amended, Initial Regulatory Flexibility Analysis (IRFAs) was
incorporated in the Notice of Proposed Rule Making (Internet Freedom
NPRM) for this proceeding. The Commission sought written public comment
on the proposals in the Internet Freedom NPRM, including comment on the
IRFA. The Commission received comments on the Internet Freedom NPRM
IRFA, which are discussed below. This present Final Regulatory
Flexibility Analysis (FRFA) conforms to the RFA.
A. Need for, and Objectives of, the Final Rules
334. In order to return the internet to the light-touch regulatory
environment that allowed investment to increase and consumers to
benefit, we return broadband internet access service to its
longstanding classification as an information service, and eliminate
several rules adopted in the Title II Order, including the general
conduct standard, the ban on paid prioritization, and the no-blocking
and no-throttling rules. We retain the transparency rule adopted in the
Open Internet Order, with modifications, while eliminating the
additional reporting obligations created in the Title II Order, the
Title II Order's direct notification requirement, and the broadband
label ``safe harbor.''
335. We also eliminate the formal complaint procedures under Part 8
of the Act, because the informal complaint procedures are sufficient.
We eliminate the other components of the enforcement regime created in
the Title II Order, including the position of Open Internet
Ombudsperson and the issuance of advisory opinions. We also return
mobile broadband internet access service to its longstanding definition
as a private mobile radio service under Section 332 of the
Communications Act.
The transparency rule we adopt is necessary because properly
tailored transparency disclosures provide valuable information to the
Commission to enable it to meet its statutory obligation to observe the
communications marketplace to monitor the introduction of new services
and technologies, and to identify and eliminate potential marketplace
barriers for the provision of information service. Such disclosures
also provide valuable information to other internet ecosystem
participants; transparency substantially reduces the possibility that
ISPs will engage in harmful practices, and it incentivizes quick
corrective measures by providers if problematic conduct is identified.
Appropriate disclosures help consumers make informed choices about
their purchase and use of broadband services. Moreover, clear
disclosures improve consumer confidence in ISPs' practices, ultimately
increasing user adoption and leading to additional investment and
innovation, while providing entrepreneurs and other small businesses
the necessary information to innovate and improve products.
336. Our enforcement changes will ensure that ISPs will be held
accountable for any violations of the transparency rule. We eliminate
the formal complaint procedures because the informal complaint
procedure, in conjunction with other redress options including consumer
protection laws, will sufficiently protect consumers. Additionally, we
eliminate the position of Open Internet Ombudsperson because the staff
from the Consumer and
[[Page 7915]]
Governmental Affairs Bureau--other than the Ombudsperson--have been
performing the Ombudsperson functions envisioned by the Title II Order.
We also eliminate the issuance of enforcement advisory opinions,
because enforcement advisory opinions do not diminish regulatory
uncertainty, particularly for small providers. Instead, they add costs
and uncertain timelines since there is no specific timeframe within
which to act, which can also inhibit innovation.
337. We return mobile broadband internet access service to its
original classification as a private mobile radio service because we
find that the definitions of the terms ``public switched network'' and
``interconnected service'' that the Commission adopted in the 1994
Second CMRS Report and Order reflect a better reading of the Act.
Accordingly, we readopt those definitions.
338. We restore the definition of interconnected service that
existed prior to the Title II Order. Prior to that Order, the term
``interconnected service'' was defined under the Commission's rules as
a service ``that gives subscribers the capability to communicate to or
receive communication from all other users on the public switched
network.'' The Title II Order modified this definition by deleting the
word ``all,'' finding that mobile broadband internet access service
should still be considered an interconnected service even if it only
enabled users to communicate with ``some'' other users of the public
switched network rather than all. We conclude that the better reading
of ``interconnected service'' is one that enables communication between
its users and all other users of the public switched network.
339. The legal basis for the rules we adopt today includes sections
3, 4, 201(b), 230, 231, 257, 303, 332, 403, 501, and 503 of the
Communications Act of 1934, as amended, 47 U.S.C. 153, 154, 201(b),
230, 231, 257, 303, 332, 403, 501, 503. The transparency rule we adopt
today relies on Section 257 of the Communications Act. Section 257
requires the Commission to make triennial reports to Congress, and
those triennial reports must identify ``market entry barriers for
entrepreneurs and other small businesses in the provision and ownership
of telecommunications services and information services.''
B. Summary of Significant Issues Raised by Public Comments to the IRFA
340. The Wireless Internet Service Providers Association (WISPA)
argued that the IRFA was incomplete and inaccurate. We find that this
FRFA sufficiently addresses WISPA's concerns and explains how we
``alleviate many of the significant financial harms on small providers
imposed by the [Title II Order].''
C. Response to Comments by the Chief Counsel for Advocacy of the Small
Business Administration
341. Pursuant to the Small Business Jobs Act of 2010, which amended
the RFA, the Commission is required to respond to any comments filed by
the Chief Counsel of the Small Business Administration (SBA), and to
provide a detailed statement of any change made to the proposed rule(s)
as a result of those comments.
342. The Chief Counsel did not file any comments in response to the
proposed rule(s) in this proceeding.
D. Description and Estimate of the Number of Small Entities To Which
the Final Rule May Apply
343. The RFA directs agencies to provide a description of and,
where feasible, an estimate of the number of small entities that may be
affected by the proposed rules, if adopted. The RFA generally defines
the term ``small entity'' as having the same meaning as the terms
``small business,'' ``small organization,'' and ``small governmental
jurisdiction.'' In addition, the term ``small business'' has the same
meaning as the term ``small business concern'' under the Small Business
Act. A small business concern is one that: (1) Is independently owned
and operated; (2) is not dominant in its field of operation; and (3)
satisfies any additional criteria established by the Small Business
Administration (SBA). Nationwide, there are a total of approximately
28.2 million small businesses, according to the SBA. A ``small
organization'' is generally ``any not-for-profit enterprise which is
independently owned and operated and is not dominant in its field.''
1. Total Small Entities
344. Small Entities, Small Organizations, Small Governmental
Jurisdictions. Our actions, over time, may affect small entities that
are not easily categorized at present. We therefore describe here, at
the outset, three comprehensive small entity size standards that could
be directly affected herein. First, while there are industry specific
size standards for small businesses that are used in the regulatory
flexibility analysis, according to data from the SBA's Office of
Advocacy, in general a small business is an independent business having
fewer than 500 employees. These types of small businesses represent
99.9 percent of all businesses in the United States which translates to
28.8 million businesses. Next, the type of small entity described as a
``small organization'' is generally ``any not-for-profit enterprise
which is independently owned and operated and is not dominant in its
field.'' Nationwide, as of August 2016, there were approximately
356,494 small organizations based on registration and tax data filed by
nonprofits with the Internal Revenue Service (IRS). Finally, the small
entity described as a ``small governmental jurisdiction'' is defined
generally as ``governments of cities, towns, townships, villages,
school districts, or special districts, with a population of less than
fifty thousand.'' U.S. Census Bureau data from the 2012 Census of
Governments indicates that there were 90,056 local governmental
jurisdictions consisting of general purpose governments and special
purpose governments in the United States. Of this number there were
37,132 General purpose governments (county, municipal and town or
township) with populations of less than 50,000 and 12,184 Special
purpose governments (independent school districts and special
districts) with populations of less than 50,000. The 2012 U.S. Census
Bureau data for most types of governments in the local government
category shows that the majority of these governments have populations
of less than 50,000. Based on this data we estimate that at least
49,316 local government jurisdictions fall in the category of ``small
governmental jurisdictions.''
2. Broadband Internet Access Service Providers
345. The rules we adopt apply to broadband internet access service
providers. The Economic Census places these firms, whose services might
include Voice over Internet Protocol (VoIP), in either of two
categories, depending on whether the service is provided over the
provider's own telecommunications facilities (e.g., cable and DSL
ISPs), or over client-supplied telecommunications connections (e.g.,
dial-up ISPs). The former are within the category of Wired
Telecommunications Carriers, which has an SBA small business size
standard of 1,500 or fewer employees. These are also labeled
``broadband.'' The latter are within the category of All Other
Telecommunications, which has a size standard of annual receipts of
$32.5 million or less. These are labeled non-broadband. Census data for
2012 show that there were 3,117 firms that operated
[[Page 7916]]
that year. Of this total, 3,083 operated with fewer than 1,000
employees. For the second category, census data for 2012 show that
there were 1,442 firms that operated for the entire year. Of those
firms, a total of 1,400 had annual receipts less than $25 million.
Consequently, we estimate that the majority of broadband internet
access service provider firms are small entities.
346. The broadband internet access service provider industry has
changed since this definition was introduced in 2007. The data cited
above may therefore include entities that no longer provide broadband
internet access service, and may exclude entities that now provide such
service. To ensure that this FRFA describes the universe of small
entities that our action might affect, we discuss in turn several
different types of entities that might be providing broadband internet
access service. We note that, although we have no specific information
on the number of small entities that provide broadband internet access
service over unlicensed spectrum, we include these entities in our
Initial Regulatory Flexibility Analysis.
3. Wireline Providers
347. Wired Telecommunications Carriers. The U.S. Census Bureau
defines this industry as ``establishments primarily engaged in
operating and/or providing access to transmission facilities and
infrastructure that they own and/or lease for the transmission of
voice, data, text, sound, and video using wired communications
networks. Transmission facilities may be based on a single technology
or a combination of technologies. Establishments in this industry use
the wired telecommunications network facilities that they operate to
provide a variety of services, such as wired telephony services,
including VoIP services, wired (cable) audio and video programming
distribution, and wired broadband internet services. By exception,
establishments providing satellite television distribution services
using facilities and infrastructure that they operate are included in
this industry.'' The SBA has developed a small business size standard
for Wired Telecommunications Carriers, which consists of all such
companies having 1,500 or fewer employees. Census data for 2012 show
that there were 3,117 firms that operated that year. Of this total,
3,083 operated with fewer than 1,000 employees. Thus, under this size
standard, the majority of firms in this industry can be considered
small.
348. Local Exchange Carriers (LECs). Neither the Commission nor the
SBA has developed a size standard for small businesses specifically
applicable to local exchange services. The closest applicable NAICS
Code category is for Wired Telecommunications Carriers, as defined in
paragraph 12 of this FRFA. Under that size standard, such a business is
small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees. Census data for 2012 show
that there were 3,117 firms that operated that year. Of this total,
3,083 operated with fewer than 1,000 employees. The Commission
therefore estimates that most providers of local exchange carrier
service are small entities that may be affected by the rules adopted.
349. Incumbent Local Exchange Carriers (incumbent LECs). Neither
the Commission nor the SBA has developed a small business size standard
specifically for incumbent local exchange services. The closest
applicable NAICS Code category is Wired Telecommunications Carriers as
defined in paragraph 17 of this FRFA. Under that size standard, such a
business is small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees. According to
Commission data, 3,117 firms operated in that year. Of this total,
3,083 operated with fewer than 1,000 employees. Consequently, the
Commission estimates that most providers of incumbent local exchange
service are small businesses that may be affected by the rules and
policies adopted. One thousand three hundred and seven (1,307)
Incumbent Local Exchange Carriers reported that they were incumbent
local exchange service providers. Of this total, an estimated 1,006
have 1,500 or fewer employees.
350. Competitive Local Exchange Carriers (Competitive LECs),
Competitive Access Providers (CAPs), Shared-Tenant Service Providers,
and Other Local Service Providers. Neither the Commission nor the SBA
has developed a small business size standard specifically for these
service providers. The appropriate NAICS Code category is Wired
Telecommunications Carriers, as defined in paragraph 17 of this FRFA.
Under that size standard, such a business is small if it has 1,500 or
fewer employees. U.S. Census data for 2012 indicate that 3,117 firms
operated during that year. Of that number, 3,083 operated with fewer
than 1,000 employees. Based on this data, the Commission concludes that
the majority of Competitive LECs, CAPs, Shared-Tenant Service
Providers, and Other Local Service Providers are small entities.
According to Commission data, 1,442 carriers reported that they were
engaged in the provision of either competitive local exchange services
or competitive access provider services. Of these 1,442 carriers, an
estimated 1,256 have 1,500 or fewer employees. In addition, 17 carriers
have reported that they are Shared-Tenant Service Providers, and all 17
are estimated to have 1,500 or fewer employees. In addition, 72
carriers have reported that they are Other Local Service Providers. Of
this total, 70 have 1,500 or fewer employees. Consequently, the
Commission estimates that most providers of competitive local exchange
service, competitive access providers, Shared-Tenant Service Providers,
and Other Local Service Providers are small entities that may be
affected by the adopted rules.
351. We have included small incumbent LECs in this present RFA
analysis. As noted above, a ``small business'' under the RFA is one
that, inter alia, meets the pertinent small business size standard
(e.g., a telephone communications business having 1,500 or fewer
employees), and ``is not dominant in its field of operation.'' The
SBA's Office of Advocacy contends that, for RFA purposes, small
incumbent LECs are not dominant in their field of operation because any
such dominance is not ``national'' in scope. We have therefore included
small incumbent LECs in this RFA analysis, although we emphasize that
this RFA action has no effect on Commission analyses and determinations
in other, non-RFA contexts.
352. Interexchange Carriers (IXCs). Neither the Commission nor the
SBA has developed a definition for Interexchange Carriers. The closest
NAICS Code category is Wired Telecommunications Carriers as defined in
paragraph 17 of this FRFA. The applicable size standard under SBA rules
is that such a business is small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees.
According to Commission data, 359 companies reported that their primary
telecommunications service activity was the provision of interexchange
services. Of this total, an estimated 317 have 1,500 or fewer employees
and 42 have more than 1,500 employees. Consequently, the Commission
estimates that the majority of interexchange service providers are
small entities that may be affected by rules adopted.
353. Operator Service Providers (OSPs). Neither the Commission nor
the SBA has developed a small business size standard specifically for
operator service providers. The appropriate size standard under SBA
rules is for the category Wired Telecommunications Carriers. Under that
size standard, such a business is small if it has 1,500 or fewer
employees. According to Commission data, 33 carriers have
[[Page 7917]]
reported that they are engaged in the provision of operator services.
Of these, an estimated 31 have 1,500 or fewer employees and two have
more than 1,500 employees. Consequently, the Commission estimates that
the majority of OSPs are small entities that may be affected by our
adopted rules.
354. Other Toll Carriers. Neither the Commission nor the SBA has
developed a definition for small businesses specifically applicable to
Other Toll Carriers. This category includes toll carriers that do not
fall within the categories of interexchange carriers, operator service
providers, prepaid calling card providers, satellite service carriers,
or toll resellers. The closest applicable NAICS Code category is for
Wired Telecommunications Carriers as defined above. Under the
applicable SBA size standard, such a business is small if it has 1,500
or fewer employees. Census data for 2012 shows that there were 3,117
firms that operated that year. Of this total, 3,083 operated with fewer
than 1,000 employees. Thus, under this category and the associated
small business size standard, the majority of Other Toll Carriers can
be considered small. According to internally developed Commission data,
284 companies reported that their primary telecommunications service
activity was the provision of other toll carriage. Of these, an
estimated 279 have 1,500 or fewer employees. Consequently, the
Commission estimates that most Other Toll Carriers are small entities
that may be affected by rules adopted pursuant to the Order.
4. Wireless Providers--Fixed and Mobile
355. The broadband internet access service provider category
covered by these rules may cover multiple wireless firms and categories
of regulated wireless services. Thus, to the extent the wireless
services listed below are used by wireless firms for broadband internet
access service, the proposed actions may have an impact on those small
businesses as set forth above and further below. In addition, for those
services subject to auctions, we note that, as a general matter, the
number of winning bidders that claim to qualify as small businesses at
the close of an auction does not necessarily represent the number of
small businesses currently in service. Also, the Commission does not
generally track subsequent business size unless, in the context of
assignments and transfers or reportable eligibility events, unjust
enrichment issues are implicated.
356. Wireless Telecommunications Carriers (except Satellite). This
industry comprises establishments engaged in operating and maintaining
switching and transmission facilities to provide communications via the
airwaves, such as cellular services, paging services, wireless internet
access, and wireless video services. The appropriate size standard
under SBA rules is that such a business is small if it has 1,500 or
fewer employees. For this industry, Census data for 2012 show that
there were 967 firms that operated for the entire year. Of this total,
955 firms had fewer than 1,000 employees. Thus under this category and
the associated size standard, the Commission estimates that the
majority of wireless telecommunications carriers (except satellite) are
small entities. Similarly, according to internally developed Commission
data, 413 carriers reported that they were engaged in the provision of
wireless telephony, including cellular service, Personal Communications
Service (PCS), and Specialized Mobile Radio (SMR) services. Of this
total, an estimated 261 have 1,500 or fewer employees. Consequently,
the Commission estimates that approximately half of these firms can be
considered small. Thus, using available data, we estimate that the
majority of wireless firms can be considered small.
357. The Commission's own data--available in its Universal
Licensing System--indicate that, as of October 25, 2016, there are 280
Cellular licensees that will be affected by our actions today. The
Commission does not know how many of these licensees are small, as the
Commission does not collect that information for these types of
entities. Similarly, according to internally developed Commission data,
413 carriers reported that they were engaged in the provision of
wireless telephony, including cellular service, Personal Communications
Service, and Specialized Mobile Radio Telephony services. Of this
total, an estimated 261 have 1,500 or fewer employees, and 152 have
more than 1,500 employees. Thus, using available data, we estimate that
the majority of wireless firms can be considered small.
358. Wireless Communications Services. This service can be used for
fixed, mobile, radiolocation, and digital audio broadcasting satellite
uses. The Commission defined ``small business'' for the wireless
communications services (WCS) auction as an entity with average gross
revenues of $40 million for each of the three preceding years, and a
``very small business'' as an entity with average gross revenues of $15
million for each of the three preceding years. The SBA has approved
these definitions.
359. 1670-1675 MHz Services. This service can be used for fixed and
mobile uses, except aeronautical mobile. An auction for one license in
the 1670-1675 MHz band was conducted in 2003. One license was awarded.
The winning bidder was not a small entity.
360. Wireless Telephony. Wireless telephony includes cellular,
personal communications services, and specialized mobile radio
telephony carriers. As noted, the SBA has developed a small business
size standard for Wireless Telecommunications Carriers (except
Satellite). Under the SBA small business size standard, a business is
small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees. According to Commission data,
413 carriers reported that they were engaged in wireless telephony. Of
these, an estimated 261 have 1,500 or fewer employees and 152 have more
than 1,500 employees. Therefore, a little less than one third of these
entities can be considered small.
361. Broadband Personal Communications Service. The broadband
personal communications services (PCS) spectrum is divided into six
frequency blocks designated A through F, and the Commission has held
auctions for each block. The Commission initially defined a ``small
business'' for C- and F-Block licenses as an entity that has average
gross revenues of $40 million or less in the three previous calendar
years. For F-Block licenses, an additional small business size standard
for ``very small business'' was added and is defined as an entity that,
together with its affiliates, has average gross revenues of not more
than $15 million for the preceding three calendar years. These small
business size standards, in the context of broadband PCS auctions, have
been approved by the SBA. No small businesses within the SBA-approved
small business size standards bid successfully for licenses in Blocks A
and B. There were 90 winning bidders that claimed small business status
in the first two C-Block auctions. A total of 93 bidders that claimed
small business status won approximately 40 percent of the 1,479
licenses in the first auction for the D, E, and F Blocks. On April 15,
1999, the Commission completed the reauction of 347 C-, D-, E-, and F-
Block licenses in Auction No. 22. Of the 57 winning bidders in that
auction, 48 claimed small business status and won 277 licenses.
362. On January 26, 2001, the Commission completed the auction of
422 C and F Block Broadband PCS licenses in Auction No. 35. Of the 35
winning bidders in that auction, 29
[[Page 7918]]
claimed small business status. Subsequent events concerning Auction 35,
including judicial and agency determinations, resulted in a total of
163 C and F Block licenses being available for grant. On February 15,
2005, the Commission completed an auction of 242 C-, D-, E-, and F-
Block licenses in Auction No. 58. Of the 24 winning bidders in that
auction, 16 claimed small business status and won 156 licenses. On May
21, 2007, the Commission completed an auction of 33 licenses in the A,
C, and F Blocks in Auction No. 71. Of the 12 winning bidders in that
auction, five claimed small business status and won 18 licenses. On
August 20, 2008, the Commission completed the auction of 20 C-, D-, E-,
and F-Block Broadband PCS licenses in Auction No. 78. Of the eight
winning bidders for Broadband PCS licenses in that auction, six claimed
small business status and won 14 licenses.
363. Specialized Mobile Radio Licenses. The Commission awards
``small entity'' bidding credits in auctions for Specialized Mobile
Radio (SMR) geographic area licenses in the 800 MHz and 900 MHz bands
to firms that had revenues of no more than $15 million in each of the
three previous calendar years. The Commission awards ``very small
entity'' bidding credits to firms that had revenues of no more than $3
million in each of the three previous calendar years. The SBA has
approved these small business size standards for the 900 MHz Service.
The Commission has held auctions for geographic area licenses in the
800 MHz and 900 MHz bands. The 900 MHz SMR auction began on December 5,
1995, and closed on April 15, 1996. Sixty bidders claiming that they
qualified as small businesses under the $15 million size standard won
263 geographic area licenses in the 900 MHz SMR band. The 800 MHz SMR
auction for the upper 200 channels began on October 28, 1997, and was
completed on December 8, 1997. Ten bidders claiming that they qualified
as small businesses under the $15 million size standard won 38
geographic area licenses for the upper 200 channels in the 800 MHz SMR
band. A second auction for the 800 MHz band was held on January 10,
2002 and closed on January 17, 2002 and included 23 BEA licenses. One
bidder claiming small business status won five licenses.
364. The auction of the 1,053 800 MHz SMR geographic area licenses
for the General Category channels began on August 16, 2000, and was
completed on September 1, 2000. Eleven bidders won 108 geographic area
licenses for the General Category channels in the 800 MHz SMR band and
qualified as small businesses under the $15 million size standard. In
an auction completed on December 5, 2000, a total of 2,800 Economic
Area licenses in the lower 80 channels of the 800 MHz SMR service were
awarded. Of the 22 winning bidders, 19 claimed small business status
and won 129 licenses. Thus, combining all four auctions, 41 winning
bidders for geographic licenses in the 800 MHz SMR band claimed status
as small businesses.
365. In addition, there are numerous incumbent site-by-site SMR
licenses and licensees with extended implementation authorizations in
the 800 and 900 MHz bands. We do not know how many firms provide 800
MHz or 900 MHz geographic area SMR service pursuant to extended
implementation authorizations, nor how many of these providers have
annual revenues of no more than $15 million. One firm has over $15
million in revenues. In addition, we do not know how many of these
firms have 1,500 or fewer employees, which is the SBA-determined size
standard. We assume, for purposes of this analysis, that all of the
remaining extended implementation authorizations are held by small
entities, as defined by the SBA.
366. Lower 700 MHz Band Licenses. The Commission previously adopted
criteria for defining three groups of small businesses for purposes of
determining their eligibility for special provisions such as bidding
credits. The Commission defined a ``small business'' as an entity that,
together with its affiliates and controlling principals, has average
gross revenues not exceeding $40 million for the preceding three years.
A ``very small business'' is defined as an entity that, together with
its affiliates and controlling principals, has average gross revenues
that are not more than $15 million for the preceding three years.
Additionally, the lower 700 MHz Service had a third category of small
business status for Metropolitan/Rural Service Area (MSA/RSA)
licenses--``entrepreneur''--which is defined as an entity that,
together with its affiliates and controlling principals, has average
gross revenues that are not more than $3 million for the preceding
three years. The SBA approved these small size standards. An auction of
740 licenses (one license in each of the 734 MSAs/RSAs and one license
in each of the six Economic Area Groupings (EAGs)) commenced on August
27, 2002, and closed on September 18, 2002. Of the 740 licenses
available for auction, 484 licenses were won by 102 winning bidders.
Seventy-two of the winning bidders claimed small business, very small
business or entrepreneur status and won a total of 329 licenses. A
second auction commenced on May 28, 2003, closed on June 13, 2003, and
included 256 licenses: 5 EAG licenses and 476 Cellular Market Area
licenses. Seventeen winning bidders claimed small or very small
business status and won 60 licenses, and nine winning bidders claimed
entrepreneur status and won 154 licenses. On July 26, 2005, the
Commission completed an auction of 5 licenses in the Lower 700 MHz band
(Auction No. 60). There were three winning bidders for five licenses.
All three winning bidders claimed small business status.
367. In 2007, the Commission reexamined its rules governing the 700
MHz band in the 700 MHz Second Report and Order. An auction of 700 MHz
licenses commenced January 24, 2008 and closed on March 18, 2008, which
included, 176 Economic Area licenses in the A Block, 734 Cellular
Market Area licenses in the B Block, and 176 EA licenses in the E
Block. Twenty winning bidders, claiming small business status (those
with attributable average annual gross revenues that exceed $15 million
and do not exceed $40 million for the preceding three years) won 49
licenses. Thirty three winning bidders claiming very small business
status (those with attributable average annual gross revenues that do
not exceed $15 million for the preceding three years) won 325 licenses.
368. Upper 700 MHz Band Licenses. In the 700 MHz Second Report and
Order, the Commission revised its rules regarding Upper 700 MHz
licenses. On January 24, 2008, the Commission commenced Auction 73 in
which several licenses in the Upper 700 MHz band were available for
licensing: 12 Regional Economic Area Grouping licenses in the C Block,
and one nationwide license in the D Block. The auction concluded on
March 18, 2008, with 3 winning bidders claiming very small business
status (those with attributable average annual gross revenues that do
not exceed $15 million for the preceding three years) and winning five
licenses.
369. 700 MHz Guard Band Licensees. In 2000, in the 700 MHz Guard
Band Order, the Commission adopted size standards for ``small
businesses'' and ``very small businesses'' for purposes of determining
their eligibility for special provisions such as bidding credits and
installment payments. A small business in this service is an entity
that, together with its affiliates and controlling principals, has
average gross revenues not exceeding $40 million for the
[[Page 7919]]
preceding three years. Additionally, a very small business is an entity
that, together with its affiliates and controlling principals, has
average gross revenues that are not more than $15 million for the
preceding three years. SBA approval of these definitions is not
required. An auction of 52 Major Economic Area licenses commenced on
September 6, 2000, and closed on September 21, 2000. Of the 104
licenses auctioned, 96 licenses were sold to nine bidders. Five of
these bidders were small businesses that won a total of 26 licenses. A
second auction of 700 MHz Guard Band licenses commenced on February 13,
2001, and closed on February 21, 2001. All eight of the licenses
auctioned were sold to three bidders. One of these bidders was a small
business that won a total of two licenses.
370. Air-Ground Radiotelephone Service. The Commission has
previously used the SBA's small business size standard applicable to
Wireless Telecommunications Carriers (except Satellite), i.e., an
entity employing no more than 1,500 persons. There are approximately
100 licensees in the Air-Ground Radiotelephone Service, and under that
definition, we estimate that almost all of them qualify as small
entities under the SBA definition. For purposes of assigning Air-Ground
Radiotelephone Service licenses through competitive bidding, the
Commission has defined ``small business'' as an entity that, together
with controlling interests and affiliates, has average annual gross
revenues for the preceding three years not exceeding $40 million. A
``very small business'' is defined as an entity that, together with
controlling interests and affiliates, has average annual gross revenues
for the preceding three years not exceeding $15 million. These
definitions were approved by the SBA. In May 2006, the Commission
completed an auction of nationwide commercial Air-Ground Radiotelephone
Service licenses in the 800 MHz band (Auction No. 65). On June 2, 2006,
the auction closed with two winning bidders winning two Air-Ground
Radiotelephone Services licenses. Neither of the winning bidders
claimed small business status.
371. AWS Services (1710-1755 MHz and 2110-2155 MHz bands (AWS-1);
1915-1920 MHz, 1995-2000 MHz, 2020-2025 MHz and 2175-2180 MHz bands
(AWS-2); 2155-2175 MHz band (AWS-3)). For the AWS-1 bands, the
Commission has defined a ``small business'' as an entity with average
annual gross revenues for the preceding three years not exceeding $40
million, and a ``very small business'' as an entity with average annual
gross revenues for the preceding three years not exceeding $15 million.
For AWS-2 and AWS-3, although we do not know for certain which entities
are likely to apply for these frequencies, we note that the AWS-1 bands
are comparable to those used for cellular service and personal
communications service. The Commission has not yet adopted size
standards for the AWS-2 or AWS-3 bands but proposes to treat both AWS-2
and AWS-3 similarly to broadband PCS service and AWS-1 service due to
the comparable capital requirements and other factors, such as issues
involved in relocating incumbents and developing markets, technologies,
and services.
372. 3650-3700 MHz band. In March 2005, the Commission released a
Report and Order and Memorandum Opinion and Order that provides for
nationwide, non-exclusive licensing of terrestrial operations,
utilizing contention-based technologies, in the 3650 MHz band (i.e.,
3650-3700 MHz). As of April 2010, more than 1270 licenses have been
granted and more than 7433 sites have been registered. The Commission
has not developed a definition of small entities applicable to 3650-
3700 MHz band nationwide, non-exclusive licensees. However, we estimate
that the majority of these licensees are Internet Access Service
Providers (ISPs) and that most of those licensees are small businesses.
373. Fixed Microwave Services. Microwave services include common
carrier, private-operational fixed, and broadcast auxiliary radio
services. They also include the Local Multipoint Distribution Service
(LMDS), the Digital Electronic Message Service (DEMS), and the 24 GHz
Service, where licensees can choose between common carrier and non-
common carrier status. At present, there are approximately 36,708
common carrier fixed licensees and 59,291 private operational-fixed
licensees and broadcast auxiliary radio licensees in the microwave
services. There are approximately 135 LMDS licensees, three DEMS
licensees, and three 24 GHz licensees. The Commission has not yet
defined a small business with respect to microwave services. For
purposes of the IRFA, we will use the SBA's definition applicable to
Wireless Telecommunications Carriers (except satellite)--i.e., an
entity with no more than 1,500 persons. Under the present and prior
categories, the SBA has deemed a wireless business to be small if it
has 1,500 or fewer employees. The Commission does not have data
specifying the number of these licensees that have more than 1,500
employees, and thus is unable at this time to estimate with greater
precision the number of fixed microwave service licensees that would
qualify as small business concerns under the SBA's small business size
standard. Consequently, the Commission estimates that there are up to
36,708 common carrier fixed licensees and up to 59,291 private
operational-fixed licensees and broadcast auxiliary radio licensees in
the microwave services that may be small and may be affected by the
rules and policies adopted herein. We note, however, that the common
carrier microwave fixed licensee category includes some large entities.
374. Broadband Radio Service and Educational Broadband Service.
Broadband Radio Service systems, previously referred to as Multipoint
Distribution Service (MDS) and Multichannel Multipoint Distribution
Service (MMDS) systems, and ``wireless cable,'' transmit video
programming to subscribers and provide two-way high speed data
operations using the microwave frequencies of the Broadband Radio
Service (BRS) and Educational Broadband Service (EBS) (previously
referred to as the Instructional Television Fixed Service (ITFS)). In
connection with the 1996 BRS auction, the Commission established a
small business size standard as an entity that had annual average gross
revenues of no more than $40 million in the previous three calendar
years. The BRS auctions resulted in 67 successful bidders obtaining
licensing opportunities for 493 Basic Trading Areas (BTAs). Of the 67
auction winners, 61 met the definition of a small business. BRS also
includes licensees of stations authorized prior to the auction. At this
time, we estimate that of the 61 small business BRS auction winners, 48
remain small business licensees. In addition to the 48 small businesses
that hold BTA authorizations, there are approximately 392 incumbent BRS
licensees that are considered small entities. After adding the number
of small business auction licensees to the number of incumbent
licensees not already counted, we find that there are currently
approximately 440 BRS licensees that are defined as small businesses
under either the SBA or the Commission's rules.
375. In 2009, the Commission conducted Auction 86, the sale of 78
licenses in the BRS areas. The Commission offered three levels of
bidding credits: (i) A bidder with attributed average annual gross
revenues that exceed $15 million and do not exceed $40 million for the
preceding three years (small business) received a
[[Page 7920]]
15 percent discount on its winning bid; (ii) a bidder with attributed
average annual gross revenues that exceed $3 million and do not exceed
$15 million for the preceding three years (very small business)
received a 25 percent discount on its winning bid; and (iii) a bidder
with attributed average annual gross revenues that do not exceed $3
million for the preceding three years (entrepreneur) received a 35
percent discount on its winning bid. Auction 86 concluded in 2009 with
the sale of 61 licenses. Of the ten winning bidders, two bidders that
claimed small business status won 4 licenses; one bidder that claimed
very small business status won three licenses; and two bidders that
claimed entrepreneur status won six licenses.
5. Satellite Service Providers
376. Satellite Telecommunications Providers. Two economic census
categories address the satellite industry. Both categories have a small
business size standard of $32.5 million or less in average annual
receipts, under SBA rules.
377. Satellite Telecommunications. This category comprises firms
``primarily engaged in providing telecommunications services to other
establishments in the telecommunications and broadcasting industries by
forwarding and receiving communications signals via a system of
satellites or reselling satellite telecommunications.'' The category
has a small business size standard of $32.5 million or less in average
annual receipts, under SBA rules. For this category, Census Bureau data
for 2012 show that there were a total of 333 firms that operated for
the entire year. Of this total, 299 firms had annual receipts of less
than $25 million. Consequently, we estimate that the majority of
satellite telecommunications providers are small entities.
378. All Other Telecommunications. ``All Other Telecommunications''
is defined as follows: ``This U.S. industry is comprised of
establishments that are primarily engaged in providing specialized
telecommunications services, such as satellite tracking, communications
telemetry, and radar station operation. This industry also includes
establishments primarily engaged in providing satellite terminal
stations and associated facilities connected with one or more
terrestrial systems and capable of transmitting telecommunications to,
and receiving telecommunications from, satellite systems.
Establishments providing internet services or voice over internet
protocol (VoIP) services via client supplied telecommunications
connections are also included in this industry.'' The SBA has developed
a small business size standard for ``All Other Telecommunications,''
which consists of all such firms with gross annual receipts of $32.5
million or less. For this category, Census Bureau data for 2012 show
that there were 1,442 firms that operated for the entire year. Of those
firms, a total of 1,400 had annual receipts less than $25 million.
Consequently, we conclude that the majority of All Other
Telecommunications firms can be considered small.
6. Cable Service Providers
379. Because Section 706 requires us to monitor the deployment of
broadband using any technology, we anticipate that some broadband
service providers may not provide telephone service. Accordingly, we
describe below other types of firms that may provide broadband
services, including cable companies, MDS providers, and utilities,
among others.
380. Cable and Other Subscription Programming. This industry
comprises establishments primarily engaged in operating studios and
facilities for the broadcasting of programs on a subscription or fee
basis. The broadcast programming is typically narrowcast in nature
(e.g., limited format, such as news, sports, education, or youth-
oriented). These establishments produce programming in their own
facilities or acquire programming from external sources. The
programming material is usually delivered to a third party, such as
cable systems or direct-to-home satellite systems, for transmission to
viewers. The SBA size standard for this industry establishes as small,
any company in this category which has annual receipts of $38.5 million
or less. According to 2012 U.S. Census Bureau data, 367 firms operated
for the entire year. Of that number, 319 operated with annual receipts
of less than $25 million a year and 48 firms operated with annual
receipts of $25 million or more. Based on this data, the Commission
estimates that the majority of firms operating in this industry are
small.
381. Cable Companies and Systems (Rate Regulation). The Commission
has developed its own small business size standards for the purpose of
cable rate regulation. Under the Commission's rules, a ``small cable
company'' is one serving 400,000 or fewer subscribers nationwide.
Industry data indicate that there are currently 4,600 active cable
systems in the United States. Of this total, all but nine cable
operators nationwide are small under the 400,000-subscriber size
standard. In addition, under the Commission's rate regulation rules, a
``small system'' is a cable system serving 15,000 or fewer subscribers.
Current Commission records show 4,600 cable systems nationwide. Of this
total, 3,900 cable systems have fewer than 15,000 subscribers, and 700
systems have 15,000 or more subscribers, based on the same records.
Thus, under this standard as well, we estimate that most cable systems
are small entities.
382. Cable System Operators (Telecom Act Standard). The
Communications Act of 1934, as amended, also contains a size standard
for small cable system operators, which is ``a cable operator that,
directly or through an affiliate, serves in the aggregate fewer than
one percent of all subscribers in the United States and is not
affiliated with any entity or entities whose gross annual revenues in
the aggregate exceed $250,000,000 are approximately 52,403,705 cable
video subscribers in the United States today. Accordingly, an operator
serving fewer than 524,037 subscribers shall be deemed a small operator
if its annual revenues, when combined with the total annual revenues of
all its affiliates, do not exceed $250 million in the aggregate. Based
on available data, we find that all but nine incumbent cable operators
are small entities under this size standard. We note that the
Commission neither requests nor collects information on whether cable
system operators are affiliated with entities whose gross annual
revenues exceed $250 million. Although it seems certain that some of
these cable system operators are affiliated with entities whose gross
annual revenues exceed $250,000,000, we are unable at this time to
estimate with greater precision the number of cable system operators
that would qualify as small cable operators under the definition in the
Communications Act.
7. All Other Telecommunications
383. ``All Other Telecommunications'' is defined as follows: ``This
U.S. industry is comprised of establishments that are primarily engaged
in providing specialized telecommunications services, such as satellite
tracking, communications telemetry, and radar station operation. This
industry also includes establishments primarily engaged in providing
satellite terminal stations and associated facilities connected with
one or more terrestrial systems and capable of transmitting
telecommunications to, and receiving telecommunications from, satellite
systems. Establishments providing internet services or voice over
internet
[[Page 7921]]
protocol (VoIP) services via client supplied telecommunications
connections are also included in this industry.'' The SBA has developed
a small business size standard for ``All Other Telecommunications,''
which consists of all such firms with gross annual receipts of $32.5
million or less. For this category, Census Bureau data for 2012 show
that there were 1,442 firms that operated for the entire year. Of those
firms, a total of 1,400 had annual receipts less than $25 million.
Consequently, we conclude that the majority of All Other
Telecommunications firms can be considered small.
E. Description of Projected Reporting, Recordkeeping, and Other
Compliance Requirements for Small Entities
384. Today's action requires broadband internet access service
providers to ``publicly disclose accurate information regarding the
network management practices, performance, and commercial terms of its
broadband internet access services sufficient to enable consumers to
make informed choices regarding the purchase and use of such services
and entrepreneurs and other small businesses to develop, market, and
maintain internet offerings.''
385. Broadband internet access service providers must disclose
performance characteristics, network practices, and commercial terms.
The required disclosures must either be posted on a publicly available,
easily accessible website, or they must be submitted to the Commission,
which will post the disclosures on a publicly available, easily
accessible website.
386. Because the disclosure requirements we adopt today eliminate
the additional reporting obligations found in the Title II Order, we
decline to provide an exemption for smaller providers at this time.
While a commenter emphasized that small broadband internet access
service providers had an even more pressing need to be classified as
information service providers, today's action applies equally to all
providers of broadband internet access service, and therefore does even
more than the initial comment requested.
F. Steps Taken To Minimize the Significant Economic Impact on Small
Entities, and Significant Alternatives Considered
387. Today's action restores broadband internet access service's
original classification as an information service. This will
significantly decrease the burdens on small entities. Additionally, the
removal of the additional reporting obligations, the direct
notification requirement, and the broadband provider safe harbor form
will minimize the burdens providers face.
388. The transparency rule we adopt today strikes an appropriate
balance by requiring ISPs to disclose information that will allow
consumers to make informed choices and that will enable the Commission
to enable it to meet its statutory obligation to observe the
communications marketplace to monitor the introduction of new services
and technologies and to identify and eliminate potential marketplace
barriers for the provision of information service, while simultaneously
freeing providers from onerous burdens that produce little public
benefit. While retaining the transparency rule, with modifications,
from the Open Internet Order, we eliminate the additional reporting
obligations, the direct notification requirements, and the broadband
label ``safe harbor,'' all of which will reduce the burdens on ISPs.
The additional reporting obligations, the direct notification
requirement, and the ``safe harbor'' all required ISPs to expend
significant resources without a corresponding gain to consumers,
entrepreneurs, or other small businesses.
389. We also eliminate several rules adopted in the Title II Order,
including the general conduct standard, the ban on paid prioritization,
and the no-blocking and no-throttling rules. We eliminate these rules
for three reasons. First, the transparency rule we adopt, in
combination with the state of broadband internet access service
competition and the antitrust and consumer protection laws, obviate the
need for conduct rules by achieving comparable benefits at lower cost.
Second, the record does not identify any legal authority to adopt
conduct rules for all ISPs, and we decline to distort the market with a
patchwork of non-uniform, limited-purpose rules. Third, scrutinizing
closely each prior conduct rule, we find that the costs of each rule
outweigh its benefits.
390. We also eliminate the position of Open Internet Ombudsperson,
the formal complaint process, and the issuance of advisory opinions,
because the work of the Open Internet Ombudsperson is more
appropriately handled by Commission staff, and because the issuance of
advisory opinions and the formal complaint process have not been shown
to provide any benefit to broadband internet access service providers
or consumers.
391. Finally, we return mobile broadband internet access service to
its original classification as a private mobile radio service and
restore the definition of interconnected service that existed prior to
the Title II Order. This will remove regulatory burdens from providers
of mobile broadband internet access service, including small providers.
G. Report to Congress
392. The Commission will send a copy of this Declaratory Ruling,
Report and Order, and Order, including this FRFA, in a report to be
sent to Congress pursuant to the SBREFA. In addition, the Commission
will send a copy of this Declaratory Ruling, Report and Order, and
Order, including the FRFA, to the Chief Counsel for Advocacy of the
SBA. A copy of the Declaratory Ruling, Report and Order, and Order, and
the FRFA (or summaries thereof) will also be published in the Federal
Register.
VII. Ordering Clauses
393. Accordingly, it is ordered that, pursuant to Sections 3, 4,
201(b), 230, 231, 257, 303, 332, 403, 501, and 503 of the
Communications Act of 1934, as amended, 47 U.S.C. 153, 154, 201(b),
230, 231, 257, 303, 332, 403, 501, 503, this Declaratory Ruling, Report
and Order, and Order is adopted.
394. It is further ordered that parts 1, 8, and 20 of the
Commission's rules are amended as set forth in the Final Rules of the
Order.
395. It is further ordered that this Declaratory Ruling, Report and
Order, and Order, including those amendments which contain new or
modified information collection requirements that require approval by
the Office of Management and Budget (OMB) under the Paperwork Reduction
Act will become effective upon the effective date announced when the
Commission publishes a document in the Federal Register announcing such
OMB approval and the effective date. It is our intention in adopting
the foregoing Declaratory Ruling and these rule changes that, if any
provision of the Declaratory Ruling or the rules, or the application
thereof to any person or circumstance, is held to be unlawful, the
remaining portions of such Declaratory Ruling and the rules not deemed
unlawful, and the application of such Declaratory Ruling and the rules
to other person or circumstances, shall remain in effect to the fullest
extent permitted by law.
396. It is further ordered that the incompas Petition to Modify
Protective Orders is denied.
[[Page 7922]]
397. It is further ordered that the National Hispanic Media
Coalition (NHMC) Motion Regarding Informal Consumer Complaints is
denied.
398. It is further ordered that the Commission's Consumer &
Governmental Affairs Bureau, Reference Information Center, shall send a
copy of this Declaratory Ruling, Report and Order, and Order to
Congress and the Government Accountability Office pursuant to the
Congressional Review Act, see 5 U.S.C. 801(a)(1)(A).
399. It is further ordered that, pursuant to 47 CFR 1.4(b)(1), the
period for filing petitions for reconsideration or petitions for
judicial review of this Declaratory Ruling, Report and Order, and Order
will commence on the date that a summary of this Declaratory Ruling,
Report and Order, and Order is published in the Federal Register.
List of Subjects in 47 CFR Parts 1, 8, and 20
Administrative practice and procedure, Cable television, Common
carriers, Communications common carriers, Reporting and recordkeeping
requirements, Satellites, Telecommunications, Telephone, Radio.
Federal Communications Commission.
Marlene H. Dortch,
Secretary, Office of the Secretary.
Final Rules
For the reasons discussed in the preamble, the Federal
Communications Commission amends 47 CFR parts 1, 8, and 20 as follows:
PART 1--PRACTICE AND PROCEDURE
0
1. The authority citation for part 1 continues to read as follows:
Authority: 47 U.S.C. 34-39, 151, 154(i), 154(j), 155, 157, 160,
201, 225, 227, 303, 309, 332, 1403, 1404, 1451, 1452, and 1455.
0
2. Amend Sec. 1.49 by revising paragraph (f)(1)(i) to read as follows:
Sec. 1.49 Specifications as to pleadings and documents.
* * * * *
(f) * * *
(1) * * *
(i) Formal complaint proceedings under section 208 of the Act and
in Sec. Sec. 1.720 through 1.736, and pole attachment complaint
proceedings under section 224 of the Act and in Sec. Sec. 1.1401
through 1.1424;
* * * * *
PART 8--INTERNET FREEDOM
0
3. The authority citation for part 8 is revised to read as follows:
Authority: 47 U.S.C. 154, 201(b), 257, and 303(r).
0
4. Amend part 8 by revising the part heading to read as set forth
above.
0
5. Revise Sec. 8.1 to read as follows:
Sec. 8.1 Transparency.
(a) Any person providing broadband internet access service shall
publicly disclose accurate information regarding the network management
practices, performance characteristics, and commercial terms of its
broadband internet access services sufficient to enable consumers to
make informed choices regarding the purchase and use of such services
and entrepreneurs and other small businesses to develop, market, and
maintain internet offerings. Such disclosure shall be made via a
publicly available, easily accessible website or through transmittal to
the Commission.
(b) Broadband internet access service is a mass-market retail
service by wire or radio that provides the capability to transmit data
to and receive data from all or substantially all internet endpoints,
including any capabilities that are incidental to and enable the
operation of the communications service, but excluding dial-up internet
access service. This term also encompasses any service that the
Commission finds to be providing a functional equivalent of the service
described in the previous sentence or that is used to evade the
protections set forth in this part.
(c) A network management practice is reasonable if it is
appropriate and tailored to achieving a legitimate network management
purpose, taking into account the particular network architecture and
technology of the broadband internet access service.
Sec. Sec. 8.2, 8.3, 8.5, 8.7, 8.9, 8.11, 8.12, 8.13, 8.14, 8.15, 8.16,
8.17, 8.18, and 8.19 [Removed]
0
6. Remove Sec. Sec. 8.2, 8.3, 8.5, 8.7, 8.9, 8.11, 8.12, 8.13, 8.14,
8.15, 8.16, 8.17, 8.18, and 8.19.
PART 20--COMMERCIAL MOBILE SERVICES
0
7. The authority citation for part 20 continues to read as follows:
Authority: 47 U.S.C. 151, 152(a) 154(i), 157, 160, 201, 214,
222, 251(e), 301, 302, 303, 303(b), 303(r), 307, 307(a), 309,
309(j)(3), 316, 316(a), 332, 610, 615, 615a, 615b, 615c, unless
otherwise noted.
0
8. Amend Sec. 20.3 by:
0
a. In the definition of ``Commercial mobile radio service,'' revising
paragraph (b);
0
b. In the definition of ``Interconnected Service,'' revising paragraph
(a); and
0
c. Revising the definition of ``Public Switched Network.''
The revisions read as follows:
Sec. 20.3 Definitions.
* * * * *
Commercial mobile radio service. * * *
* * * * *
(b) The functional equivalent of such a mobile service described in
paragraph (a) of this definition.
* * * * *
Interconnected Service. * * *
(a) That is interconnected with the public switched network, or
interconnected with the public switched network through an
interconnected service provider, that gives subscribers the capability
to communicate to or receive communication from all other users on the
public switched network; or
* * * * *
Public Switched Network. Any common carrier switched network,
whether by wire or radio, including local exchange carriers,
interexchange carriers, and mobile service providers, that uses the
North American Numbering Plan in connection with the provision of
switched services.
* * * * *
[FR Doc. 2018-03464 Filed 2-21-18; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6712-01-P