Structure and Practices of the Video Relay Services Program, 39673-39683 [2017-17225]
Download as PDF
Federal Register / Vol. 82, No. 161 / Tuesday, August 22, 2017 / Rules and Regulations
Subpart LLL—National Emission
Standards for Hazardous Air Pollutants
From the Portland Cement
Manufacturing Industry
2. Section 63.1349 is amended by
adding paragraph (b)(6)(v)(H) to read as
follows:
■
§ 63.1349 Performance testing
requirements.
*
*
*
*
*
(b) * * *
(6) * * *
(v) * * *
(H) Paragraph (b)(6)(v) of this section
expires on July 25, 2017 at which time
the owner or operator must demonstrate
compliance with paragraphs (b)(6)(i),
(ii), or (iii).
*
*
*
*
*
■ 3. Section 63.1350 is amended by
revising paragraph (l)(4) introductory
text to read as follows:
§ 63.1350
Monitoring requirements.
*
*
*
*
*
(l) * * *
(4) If you monitor continuous
performance through the use of an HCl
CPMS according to paragraphs
(b)(6)(v)(A) through (H) of § 63.1349, for
any exceedance of the 30 kiln operating
day HCl CPMS average value from the
established operating limit, you must:
*
*
*
*
*
[FR Doc. 2017–17624 Filed 8–21–17; 8:45 am]
Congressional Review Act
The Commission sent a copy of
document FCC 17–86 to Congress and
the Government Accountability Office
pursuant to the Congressional Review
Act, see 5 U.S.C. 801(a)(1)(A).
BILLING CODE 6560–50–P
FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS
COMMISSION
47 CFR Part 64
[CG Docket Nos. 10–51 and 03–123; FCC
17–86]
Structure and Practices of the Video
Relay Services Program
Federal Communications
Commission.
ACTION: Final rule.
AGENCY:
In this document, the
Commission adopts a four-year rate plan
to compensate video relay service (VRS)
providers, amends its rules to permitserver based routing for VRS and pointto-point calls, authorizes the continued
use of money from the
Telecommunications Relay Service
(TRS) Fund for Commission-supervised
research and development, eliminates
rules providing for a neutral video
communications service platform, and
reinstates the effectiveness of the rule
incorporating the VRS Interoperability
Profile technical standard.
sradovich on DSK3GMQ082PROD with RULES
SUMMARY:
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:39 Aug 21, 2017
Jkt 241001
Effective September 21, 2017.
The compliance date for 47 CFR
64.621(b)(1) is December 20, 2017. The
incorporation by reference of certain
publication listed in the rules was
approved by the Director of the Federal
Register as of May 30, 2017.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: Bob
Aldrich, Consumer and Governmental
Affairs Bureau at: (202) 418–0996, email
Robert.Aldrich@fcc.gov, or Eliot
Greenwald, Consumer and
Governmental Affairs Bureau at: (202)
418–2235, email Eliot.Greenwald@
fcc.gov.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: This is a
summary of the Commission’s Report
and Order and Order, FCC 17–86,
adopted and released on July 6, 2017, in
CG Docket Nos. 10–51 and 03–123. The
full text of this document will be
available for public inspection and
copying via the Commission’s
Electronic Comment Filing System
(ECFS), and during regular business
hours at the FCC Reference Information
Center, Portals II, 445 12th Street SW.,
Room CY–A257, Washington, DC 20554.
To request materials in accessible
formats for people with disabilities
(Braille, large print, electronic files,
audio format), send an email to fcc504@
fcc.gov or call the Consumer and
Governmental Affairs Bureau at (202)
418–0530 (voice), (844) 432–2272
(videophone), or (202) 418–0432 (TTY).
DATES:
Final Paperwork Reduction Act of 1995
Analysis
Document FCC 17–86 does not
contain any new or modified
information collection requirements
subject to the Paperwork Reduction Act
of 1995, Pub. L. 104–13. In addition,
therefore, it does not contain any new
or modified information collection
burden for small business concerns with
fewer than 25 employees, pursuant to
the Small Business Paperwork Relief
Act of 2002, Pub. L. 107–198, see 44
U.S.C. 3506(c)(4).
Synopsis
VRS Compensation—Allowable Cost
Categories
1. In the Further Notice of Proposed
Rulemaking (FNPRM), FCC 17–26,
published at 82 FR 17613, April 12,
2017, the Commission stated its
intention not to reopen questions
concerning the categories of expenses
PO 00000
Frm 00019
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
39673
that should be considered allowable
costs for VRS compensation. Various
parties commenting in this proceeding
nonetheless urge that the Commission
re-open the matter of allowing costs
associated with customer premise
equipment (CPE), numbering, outreach,
and research and development (R&D). In
addition, Sorenson Communications,
LLC (Sorenson) raises new concerns
about allowing compensation for
imputed intellectual property. These
issues are beyond the scope of the
rulemaking. The Commission has
previously considered and disallowed
compensation for each of these
categories, except intellectual property,
which is addressed below.
2. No reason to reopen previously
settled disallowance issues. No party
provides a compelling reason to reopen
the above issues in this proceeding,
especially in the absence of
Administrative Procedure Act (APA)
notice. The Commission does not agree
that circumstances have changed
dramatically and sees no material
difference from prior proceedings where
these issues were addressed.
3. Even if the issues were not already
settled and there was APA notice
regarding them, the Commission would
not be persuaded by arguments to
expand allowable costs. Equalizing all
VRS-related costs to a voice telephone
user’s costs is not part of the
Commission’s mandate under section
225 of the Act. Congressional intent to
equalize either network access rates or
equipment costs for TRS and voice
service users is not evident in the text
of this narrowly drawn provision, its
surrounding context, or its legislative
history. In 1990, the year of section
225’s enactment, all TRS calls took
place between individuals who used
TTYs and voice users. But the high costs
of TTY service rates and equipment
were matters of public awareness and
were being addressed through state and
federal action outside the relay
requirements of section 225 of the Act.
Regarding service costs, the plain text of
this section demonstrates that it solely
was intended to prevent relay users
from incurring the added costs of
routing TRS calls through remote relay
centers that lie outside the geographical
locations of the parties to a relay call,
and nothing more. Congress had
knowledge about, and ample
opportunity to direct the Commission to
equalize telephone service costs for TTY
users at the time of section 225’s
enactment, yet it specifically chose not
to do so. Accordingly, the discrepancy
between the higher service costs for a
broadband connection needed to
achieve access to VRS and the costs of
E:\FR\FM\22AUR1.SGM
22AUR1
sradovich on DSK3GMQ082PROD with RULES
39674
Federal Register / Vol. 82, No. 161 / Tuesday, August 22, 2017 / Rules and Regulations
telephone service incurred by voice
users was not a matter intended to be
addressed by section 225 of the Act.
4. Similarly, at the time of section
225’s enactment, it was quite evident
that the cost of end user equipment
needed to complete TRS calls would be
significantly greater than the equipment
costs incurred by voice telephone users.
The average cost for a TTY was $600–
$1000, a prohibitive amount for many
individuals with low incomes. Again,
however, there is simply no indication
in section 225 of the Act or its
legislative history of an intent by
Congress to require the Commission to
use the TRS Fund or any other
mechanism to equalize such equipment
costs. Rather, states developed local
programs to distribute TTYs and other
specialized customer premises
equipment to low income and other
eligible individuals with disabilities.
5. Further, disallowance of end user
equipment costs from compensable
expenses does not discourage the
development of improved technology.
Rather, compensation to providers for
the provision of free equipment runs
counter to promoting the use of new
mobile and other technologies that are
available for use with VRS. The
Commission has undertaken extensive
efforts to expand the availability of
interoperable off-the-shelf Internet
Protocol (IP) enabled devices for VRS
use, so that individuals who use these
services can reduce their dependence on
VRS equipment specifically designed
for a particular provider’s network.
Providers increasingly run their own
software on off-the-shelf mobile devices,
tablets, desktop personal computers,
and laptops, reducing the need for
specialized, stand-alone VRS
equipment. Because the Commission’s
rules require that all providers support
a common standard for relay user
equipment (in addition to their own
proprietary standards), the Commission
has made it possible for the software
developed according to such standard to
work on all provider networks, thus
making it more attractive for third
parties to develop VRS software. These
actions demonstrate a concerted effort
by the Commission to further section
225’s mandate to encourage the use of
new and innovative technology.
6. By not authorizing recovery of the
costs of VRS CPE, the Commission
avoids offering preferential subsidies to
certain VRS providers (i.e., those who
rely on the free provision of expensive,
dedicated videophones and other
equipment to attract and retain VRS
consumers for their branded services) to
the exclusion of others, as well as
avoids encouraging providers to engage
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:39 Aug 21, 2017
Jkt 241001
in free CPE giveaways as incentives to
use their services. The Commission
believes that if VRS providers are to
compete for customers, it is preferable
for such competition to take place with
respect to the quality of their services—
which was the intended purpose of
section 225 of the Act—not the
equipment they can afford to distribute.
The Commission finds no basis for
departing from Commission precedent,
and therefore again declines to allow
use of TRS funds to support VRS
providers’ equipment costs.
7. Intellectual Property. The
Commission concludes that a provider
that develops its own intellectual
property is not entitled to have the
imputed value of that property included
in allowable costs. First, the
Commission has not previously allowed
compensation for the imputed value of
TRS providers’ property, whether
tangible or intangible, and the
Commission sees no reason to do so
under a methodology that is based on
compensating providers for their actual
expenses. Any attempt to value
intellectual property would necessarily
be speculative and highly inexact,
especially in the absence of evidence
based on arm’s length marketplace
transactions involving such property.
Second, as noted above, to the extent
that a provider engages in R&D to
develop VRS technologies whose
purpose is to meet the Commission’s
mandatory minimum standards, it is
already permitted to recover those
expenses from the TRS Fund. To also
compensate a provider for the imputed
value of such technology would be
duplicative at best. Third, the
Commission finds unconvincing the
suggestion of an analogy between costs
incurred by a TRS provider to license
technology from third parties and the
imputation of a licensing fee to be
‘‘paid’’ by a TRS provider to itself. The
Commission’s cost-of-service
methodology appropriately assesses the
cost of VRS based on provider’s actual
expenses, not hypothetical expenses
that a provider might have incurred had
it chosen to purchase technology from
third parties. When a VRS provider
chooses to develop its own VRS
technologies rather than license them
from others, it is reasonable to assume
that the provider decided that such selfprovisioning would enable it to provide
service more effectively and at lower
cost. It is likewise reasonable and
appropriate for the Commission to
assess a provider’s costs based on its
actual expenditures rather than
hypothetical, more costly expenditures
PO 00000
Frm 00020
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
that it might have made but chose not
to.
8. In effect, the argument for recovery
of the imputed value of a TRS provider’s
intellectual property appears to be a
way of arguing that VRS providers
should be able to gain additional profit
for what they have invested in R&D.
Although the Commission allows
providers to recover their reasonable
expenses of providing TRS, in prior
decisions it has disallowed claims for
‘‘profit’’ in excess of a reasonable
allowance for the cost of raising capital.
Although in the section following the
Commission modifies the method of
estimating capital costs by adopting an
‘‘operating margin’’ approach that will
allow providers greater opportunity to
recover such costs, the Commission
does not thereby authorize providers to
recover additional ‘‘markup’’ or profit
that goes beyond such reasonable
allowance.
Capital Cost Recovery/Operating Margin
9. Replacing return on investment
with operating margin. In light of VRS
providers’ concerns about the adequacy
of the 11.25% allowed return on plant
investment for capital cost recovery in
an industry with very little plant
investment, the Commission adopts its
proposal in the FNPRM to replace the
current rate-of-return approach to
capital cost recovery with an operating
margin approach, allowing recovery of a
specified percentage of allowable
expenses.
10. Setting an allowed operating
margin. There is wide variation among
average operating margins of different
industry sectors, as well as between
operating margins for particular
companies and time periods. Sorenson
provides a list of adjusted EBITDA
margins for 20 ‘‘leading publicly traded
information technology consulting
companies,’’ which Sorenson states is
based on data reported by Bloomberg on
U.S.-listed public companies with a
market cap of at least $1 billion and
with 100% of their revenue derived
from ‘‘IT Services.’’ Sorenson notes that
the unweighted average margin for the
companies on this list is 15.9%.
11. The Commission concludes that
consideration of operating margins
earned in analogous industries may be
a reasonable approach to setting an
allowed operating margin for VRS
providers. However, information
technology (IT) consulting companies
are not sufficiently analogous to VRS
providers for their operating margins to
serve as a reasonable proxy. Unlike IT
consulting companies, the bulk of VRS
costs are labor costs, primarily salaries
and benefits for interpreters, who need
E:\FR\FM\22AUR1.SGM
22AUR1
Federal Register / Vol. 82, No. 161 / Tuesday, August 22, 2017 / Rules and Regulations
sradovich on DSK3GMQ082PROD with RULES
not be highly skilled in technology. The
Census Bureau’s survey of public
companies’ financial data for North
American Industry Classification
System (NAICS) Code 541, defined as
‘‘Professional, Scientific, and Technical
Services,’’ but excluding legal, shows
that average quarterly pre-tax operating
margins for this industry sector between
2013 and 2016 ranged from 1.8% (in
1Q2016) to 7.9% (in 2Q2013), averaging
4.6% in the 2013–16 period as a whole
and 3.2% in 2016. For NAICS 5419, a
subsector that includes translation and
interpretation services but excludes
various less analogous industry
segments such as accounting,
architectural and engineering, and
computer systems design services, the
average operating margin for the public
firms included in the Census Bureau’s
survey ranged from 3.9% to 12.2% for
the 2013–16 period and averaged 7.4%
in the 2013–16 period as a whole and
7.6% in 2016. Government contractors
are another category that may
reasonably be viewed as analogous to
VRS providers in that they are paid by
the government for providing services
mandated by law or otherwise closely
supervised by a government entity. In
five surveys of government contractors
by Grant Thornton, conducted between
2009 and 2015, the majority of
respondents consistently reported profit
rates before interest and taxes between
1% and 10%, with the median profit
rate in the neighborhood of 6%.
12. Selecting an operating margin
from among this wealth of data
regarding arguably analogous industry
sectors is not subject to precise
determination. The Commission notes
that for 2016 (or 2015, in the case of
government contractors, as that was the
most recent year surveyed), none of the
industry sector surveys described above,
other than the one cited by Sorenson,
had average operating margins greater
than 7.6%, and that even the high
technology firms cited by Sorenson have
a median operating margin of only
12.35%. Based on the current record,
and in light of the Commission’s
statutory mandate to ensure that VRS is
made available ‘‘to the extent possible,
and in the most efficient manner,’’ the
Commission concludes that the range of
7.6% to 12.35% represents the ‘‘zone of
reasonableness’’ of an allowable
operating margin for VRS providers.
Compensation Rate Structure
13. Over the last four years, the
Commission has observed the results of
its 2013 structural reform and rate
initiatives, including the effects on
provider incentives, to the extent those
can be discerned. The 2013 plan
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:39 Aug 21, 2017
Jkt 241001
provided for reducing the rate gap
between highest- and lowest-priced
tiers, with the ultimate expectation that
the tiered rate structure eventually
would be replaced by a unitary
compensation rate for all minutes,
which would be set either directly or by
proxy based on competitive bidding.
This expectation was, in turn, based on
the assumption that structural reforms,
such as effective interoperability and
portability standards and the
establishment of a neutral routing
platform would generate a ‘‘more
competition-friendly environment’’ for
small providers. There was also an
expectation that, pending the
completion of such structural reforms,
the temporary continuation of a tiered
rate structure would both encourage
improvements in efficiency and ensure
that smaller providers ‘‘have a
reasonable opportunity to compete
effectively during the transition and to
achieve or maintain the necessary scale
to compete effectively after structural
reforms are implemented.’’ Structure
and Practices of the Video Relay Service
Program; Telecommunications Relay
Services and Speech-to-Speech Services
for Individuals With Hearing and
Speech Disabilities, Report and Order,
FCC 13–82, published at 78 FR 40581,
July 5, 2013 (2013 VRS Reform Order).
14. The record confirms that most of
these underlying expectations and
assumptions have not been borne out by
experience. First, a number of the
Commission’s expectations regarding
the pace and content of structural
reforms have proven to be overly
optimistic. Improved interoperability
standards were not incorporated into
the Commission’s rules until this year,
and some aspects of equipment
portability, which was expected to
improve the competitiveness of the VRS
market by facilitating consumers’ use of
inexpensive, off-the-shelf devices, have
yet to secure consensus from the VRS
industry. Further, the neutral video
communications platform, which the
2013 VRS Reform Order envisioned as
a key element in enabling small
providers to compete effectively, proved
to be impracticable. These
developments disprove the
Commission’s original assumption that
structural reforms would be far enough
advanced to enable the elimination of
tiered rates and the introduction of a
market-based methodology upon the
expiration of the 2013 compensation
plan.
15. Second, provider cost reports
overall do not show the major
improvements in smaller providers’
efficiency that the Commission assumed
were possible. With the ‘‘glide path’’
PO 00000
Frm 00021
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
39675
reductions in VRS compensation rates,
providers have been under pressure to
improve efficiency, and the record
indicates that certain providers have
taken significant measures to do so. The
weighted average of historical perminute costs reported by VRS providers
has declined from 2013 to 2016;
however, the decline has been relatively
modest, compared to the period from
2009 to 2012, when average per-minute
costs declined by more than $1.00 per
minute. Thus, while it appears that
providers have achieved some efficiency
improvements, other factors, such as the
lack of full interoperability, may have
limited their success. As a result, the
Commission’s expectation that smaller
VRS providers would be able to make
substantial improvements in efficiency
within the past four-year period was not
fulfilled.
16. Third, updated VRS demand data
confirm that the VRS market structure is
largely unchanged since 2013, when
‘‘Sorenson provide[d] about 80% of the
VRS minutes logged every month, and
its two principal competitors each
provide[d] another five to ten percent.’’
Since then, the two cited competitors of
Sorenson have merged, but it is too
early to predict how that merger will
affect the viability of competition in the
VRS market (other than reducing the
total number of competitors from five to
four). What is clear, however, is that
competitors have not made significant
inroads into Sorenson’s market share,
and no VRS provider has been able to
grow significantly so as to achieve ‘‘the
necessary scale to compete effectively.’’
17. As a consequence of these
developments, there remain vast
differences in the per-minute costs of
VRS providers, which roughly track the
vastly different market shares of each
current provider. As long as such
lopsided cost structures persist, it seems
highly unlikely that any of the nondominant VRS providers can compete
`
successfully to gain market share vis-avis the largest, least-cost provider.
18. In the face of these unfulfilled
expectations and assumptions, the
Commission must choose from a
number of alternative courses to take.
One possible course would be to seek to
maximize efficiency by transitioning to
a single rate set at the level of the
allowable costs of the lowest-cost
provider, or alternatively, at the level of
the average allowable costs for the VRS
industry. This approach would reduce
the cost burden on the TRS Fund, at
least in the short term, but, given the
current disparate cost structures in the
VRS market, also would be likely to
eliminate all VRS competition. The
Commission has consistently sought to
E:\FR\FM\22AUR1.SGM
22AUR1
sradovich on DSK3GMQ082PROD with RULES
39676
Federal Register / Vol. 82, No. 161 / Tuesday, August 22, 2017 / Rules and Regulations
encourage and preserve the availability
of a competitive choice for VRS users,
because it ensures a range of service
offerings analogous to that afforded
voice service users and because it
provides a competitive incentive to
improve VRS offerings. Further, the
continuing presence of such competitive
offerings is likely to encourage the
lowest-cost provider to maintain higher
standards of service quality than if it
faced no competition. Thus, if the
Commission was to allow VRS
competition to be extinguished, for the
sake of increasing the efficiency of VRS,
the Commission would risk depriving
users of functionally equivalent VRS.
Because the Commission believes that,
in the current circumstances, the
benefits of such a rate reduction,
through increased efficiency, are not
worth the risks to functional
equivalence associated with eliminating
competitive choice, the Commission did
not propose this course as an
alternative, and no party advocates it.
19. A second alternative would be to
transition to a single rate set at the cost
level of some higher-cost provider—
most likely the next-lowest-cost
provider. Due to the current imbalance
among VRS providers’ cost structures,
however, this method would be likely to
result in greatly increased TRS Fund
expenditures, because the most efficient
provider—with the overwhelming bulk
of minutes—would be compensated at a
rate far in excess of its actual costs.
Such inefficient use of TRS Fund
resources is not permitted by section
225 of the Act if there is a more efficient
method of ensuring the availability of
functionally equivalent service. In
addition, by generating an extremely
uneven set of operating margins—huge
windfall profits for one provider and
minimally sufficient margins or actual
operating losses for the others, taking
this approach seems likely to doom any
prospect of the VRS market evolving to
a more competitive structure. Indeed,
adopting this approach, as a practical
matter, would inevitably eliminate two
of the four existing VRS competitors. A
single rate could not be set high enough
to allow a third provider to remain in
the market without raising TRS Fund
expenditures and allowing the windfall
profits for lower-cost providers to
achieve astronomical levels.
20. For these reasons, the Commission
concludes that the alternative proposed
in the FNPRM—maintaining a tiered
rate structure for the next four years—
is the best available alternative at
present. Compared with any practicable
single-rate approach, as further
explained below, a tiered rate approach
is most likely to ensure that functionally
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:39 Aug 21, 2017
Jkt 241001
equivalent VRS remains available and is
provided in the most efficient manner
with respect to TRS Fund resources.
21. First, the application of tiered
rates rather than a single rate will help
ensure that there continue to be
competitive options for VRS users, an
objective that takes on special
importance at this time, in light of the
recent attrition in the VRS market.
Although there were six independently
owned providers at the time of the 2013
VRS Reform Order, this number has
since been reduced to four. The
presence of multiple competitors, even
if less efficient than the lowest-cost
provider, may enhance functional
equivalence by ensuring that VRS users
have a choice among diverse service
offerings. Further attrition, which would
be inevitable if the Commission sets a
single rate at any realistic level, would
further limit the ability of consumers to
select providers based on service quality
and features, and would make the
continuing availability of any
competitive choice less certain, eroding
the Commission’s ability to ensure the
availability of functionally equivalent
service. In these circumstances, to the
extent that a tiered rate structure is more
effective than a single rate in preventing
further erosion of the competitiveness of
the VRS environment, it may be
justifiable on that ground alone, even if
overall efficiency would be somewhat
reduced.
22. Moreover, the record indicates
that, at this time, a tiered rate structure
is more likely than a single-rate
structure to improve the efficiency with
which the TRS Fund supports VRS.
Given the major disparities in service
provider size and cost structure, tiered
rates enable the Commission to reduce
waste of TRS Fund resources by limiting
compensation that is excessive in
relation to a provider’s actual costs.
Thus, the Commission is not persuaded
that a tiered rate structure, by allowing
payment of a higher effective
compensation rate to less efficient VRS
providers, necessarily contravenes the
mandate that VRS be available in the
most efficient manner. While the
mandate is for the Commission to
ensure the availability of VRS in the
most efficient manner, the Commission
must measure such efficiency by
comparing the overall expenditures
from the TRS Fund the Commission has
established for that purpose, with the
overall results achieved by such
expenditures in terms of TRS
availability and functional equivalence.
A single rate structure fails this test of
efficiency because it would cost the TRS
Fund more in overall compensation
PO 00000
Frm 00022
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
than the tiered rate structure the
Commission adopts.
23. Further, the Commission must
consider the value users get for the
compensation paid to providers, and
may take into consideration the extent
to which the participation of less
efficient providers produces other
benefits in the way of improved services
for consumers. In this regard, on
numerous occasions, the Commission
has made clear that there are benefits in
supporting less efficient providers that
meet the needs of niche populations,
including people who are deaf-blind or
speak Spanish, enabling the entrance of
new companies that can introduce
technological innovations into the VRS
program, and ensuring that consumers
with hearing and speech disabilities can
select among multiple VRS providers—
just as voice telephone users do. While
the Commission is obligated to ensure
the efficiency of the VRS program, it
cannot sacrifice functional equivalency
in doing so. Moreover, it is the
Commission’s statutory obligation not to
merely seek a short-term savings in an
accounting sense; rather the
Commission must consider the
consequences of its actions in the long
run. By supporting the continued
participation of multiple providers, a
tiered rate structure can help to prevent
the VRS marketplace from devolving
into a monopoly environment, thereby
providing the Commission with much
needed flexibility to consider other
approaches that may improve efficiency.
For example, one option the
Commission may want to consider in
the future is a reverse auction, in which
multiple providers bid for offering
service at the most efficient levels; but
such an approach would not be feasible
if all providers except one have been
driven out of the market. A tiered rate
structure allows the Commission to set
rates that permit each provider an
opportunity to recover its reasonable
costs of providing VRS, without
overcompensating those providers who
have lower actual costs because, for
example, they have reached a more
efficient scale of operations.
24. The Commission also does not
agree that tiered rate structures
necessarily detract from providers’
incentives to grow and increase their
efficiency. As to growth incentives,
while there could theoretically be a risk
that a provider would ‘‘put the brakes
on’’ its growth as it approached a tier
boundary, a review of each providers’
compensable minutes over the last few
years does not suggest that providers’
growth rates have been affected as their
minutes approach a tier boundary.
Moreover, to the extent there is such a
E:\FR\FM\22AUR1.SGM
22AUR1
sradovich on DSK3GMQ082PROD with RULES
Federal Register / Vol. 82, No. 161 / Tuesday, August 22, 2017 / Rules and Regulations
risk of generating perverse incentives,
the Commission believes it can be
effectively addressed by ensuring that
tier boundaries are wide enough to
cover a provider’s likely growth during
the life of the rate plan. As to efficiency
incentives, because rates are being set
for a period of several years, providers
will have an incentive to reduce
unnecessary costs so they can increase
profits and minimize losses.
25. Further, the tiers set under this
structure are not provider-specific.
Rather, each tier is equally applicable to
any provider’s minutes that fall within
that tier. Accordingly, under the tier
structure the Commission adopts, the
provider with both relatively large and
relatively small volumes of minutes are
each compensated at the higher (Tier I)
rate for their first 1 million minutes, at
a lower (Tier II) rate for additional
minutes between 1,000,000 and
2,500,000, and at the lowest (Tier III)
rate for any minutes over 2,500,000.
26. The Commission also declines to
adopt at this time a plan for
transitioning from tiered rates to a single
rate structure. The anticipated
developments that the Commission
thought would eliminate any need for
tiered rates have not materialized. Not
only have structural reforms been
delayed and reduced in scope, but
expected gains in individual provider
efficiency have not occurred, the largest
VRS provider’s current market share
remains approximately the same, and
there continue to be wide disparities
among providers’ cost structures. Thus,
the Commission’s experience to date
does not provide sufficient confidence
that transitioning to a single rate
structure would be consistent with
preserving the benefits of competition
and ensuring the availability of VRS in
the most efficient manner. With
additional time, this situation may
change. The full implementation of
competition-promoting interoperability
and portability standards, as well as the
introduction of some new reforms in
other areas, may offer greater
opportunities for providers to compete
more effectively with one another.
Additionally, the Commission is
currently gathering comment on service
quality metrics, which, when defined,
measured, and published, will enhance
VRS competition by enabling consumers
to make more informed decisions in
their selection of their VRS providers.
At a later time, the Commission can
revisit the compensation rate structure
issue as appropriate in light of such
developments.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:39 Aug 21, 2017
Jkt 241001
Alternative Approaches
27. The Commission concludes that
alternative approaches to setting VRS
rates proposed in the FNPRM, including
reliance on price caps, market-price
benchmarks, a reverse auction, and
direct provision of VRS by common
carriers, should not be adopted at this
time.
28. Price caps. It is premature, at best,
to commit to a price cap approach that
involves setting an initial, single rate
based on, for example, the costs of a
‘‘reasonably efficient provider.’’ Setting
a single rate at any level that permits
more than one provider to remain in the
market would provide windfall profits
to the lowest-cost provider, and the
wasteful costs that such windfall profits
would impose on the TRS Fund would
be extremely high given the disparate
cost structures of the current providers.
Such costs will be imposed regardless of
whether the single rate is set under a
traditional cost-of-service methodology
or as the ‘‘initializing’’ rate to kick off
a price cap plan. Further, the
Commission does not perceive any way
in which price caps could significantly
ameliorate the competition and
inefficiency disadvantages the
Commission has identified above that
lead it to reject a single-rate approach.
The multi-year, tiered transition plan
being adopted will provide many of the
same benefits as a price cap, such as
predictability in rates and incentives to
become more efficient. In addition,
given that the weighted average of
provider’s historical costs has declined
measurably over the last four years, the
Commission does not believe that the
use of such indices is necessary at this
time to ensure that VRS providers can
continue to recover their reasonable
allowable costs, including a reasonable
operating margin, over the next four
years. Towards the end of the 2017–21
rate plan, there will be another
opportunity to examine whether a price
cap approach should be adopted in
conjunction with whatever rate
structure approach is selected for the
next plan to maintain efficiency
incentives going forward.
29. Reverse auction. Sorenson
advocates the use of a reverse auction to
set VRS rates, citing as models the
auctions authorized by the Federal
Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC)
to set rates for supplying electricity, as
well as those conducted by this
Commission to allocate support for
Mobility Funds and to select recipients
of support under the Rural Broadband
Experiments. However, the auction
proposed by Sorenson differs
significantly from these examples. The
PO 00000
Frm 00023
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
39677
FERC and Commission auctions
involved bidding for both price and
quantity of the service to be supplied,
while Sorenson’s VRS proposal would
require providers to bid a price that is
not tied to a specific quantity.
Additionally, the Commission auctions
sought selection of a single provider for
each service area, rather than multiple
providers as in the VRS market. If a
provider has no guarantee of serving a
fixed number of minutes, each
provider’s bid will likely be based on
current costs associated with the current
number of minutes they provide at the
time of bidding. Thus, while Sorenson
argues that a reverse auction would
promote competition, encourage greater
efficiencies, and provide stability, it
seems equally or more likely to have the
opposite effect—producing a VRS rate
that is either well above the average cost
of providing service, or so low as to
keep currently higher cost providers
from continuing or new entrants from
joining the market. The reverse auction
proposal thus suffers from the same
defects as other single-rate proposals—
it forces a choice between setting a
single rate so low as to preclude
effective competition and setting it so
high as to provide wasteful, windfall
profits to the lowest-cost provider. In
light of the absence of analogous models
for successful implementation, and the
other issues discussed above, the
Commission declines to pursue a
reverse auction approach at this time.
The Commission does not rule out
exploring this type of approach in the
future, however, should new
developments warrant revisiting it.
30. Direct provision or procurement of
VRS by common carriers. The
Commission also finds little benefit at
this time in the alternative of
terminating TRS Fund support for VRS
and, instead, requiring common carriers
to provide VRS directly or through
contracts with TRS providers. Sorenson
offers no supporting evidence for its
claim that common carriers and other
voice service providers could provide
VRS more efficiently on a direct basis
than indirectly, through their
contributions to the TRS Fund. Further,
no carrier has commented favorably on
this proposal, while a carrier trade
association, USTelecom, affirmatively
opposes it. Accordingly, at the present
time, the Commission has no basis to
conclude that direct provision of VRS
would advance the mandate to provide
VRS in the most efficient manner or
reduce the burden on TRS Fund
contributors. Further, the Commission
agrees with the non-dominant providers
that competition and consumer choice
E:\FR\FM\22AUR1.SGM
22AUR1
39678
Federal Register / Vol. 82, No. 161 / Tuesday, August 22, 2017 / Rules and Regulations
sradovich on DSK3GMQ082PROD with RULES
might not survive a transition to a
direct-provision or direct-procurement
approach. It may well be that common
carriers would simply choose to work
with the dominant, low-cost provider,
rather than attempt to maintain provider
choice for consumers.
31. Market-based pricing generally.
While in 2013 the Commission
indicated a strong interest in exploring
a market-based approach, it did not
commit to adopting any market-based
approach, much less one that could
prove less effective than cost-based
alternatives for meeting the objectives of
section 225 of the Act. Moreover, the
market-based schemes proposed in
2013, which assumed there would be a
transition to a single market-based rate,
no longer appear to be as viable today
as they did to the Commission at that
time. Those proposals relied on the
expected availability of pricing
benchmarks that would in turn result
from the establishment of a neutral
video communications service platform.
This platform has not been built, and
based on the unsuccessful initial request
for proposals for the platform and the
general lack of interest in it shown by
most existing providers, the
Commission has decided not to move
forward with its original plan to build
this platform. Similarly, support is also
lacking for the other market-oriented
idea proposed by the Commission in
2013: an auction of calls to certain
telephone numbers receiving a high
volume of VRS calls.
Tier Structure and Rate Levels
32. Emergent rate. The Commission
adopts its proposal to add an emergent
rate to the tiered rate structure,
applicable solely to providers that have
no more than 500,000 total monthly
minutes as of July 1, 2017. The
Commission concludes that a separate
rate structure for such providers is
appropriate for a limited period to take
into account the generally much higher
cost of service for very small providers,
encourage new entry into the program,
and give such providers and new
entrants appropriate incentives to grow.
Rather than view an emergent rate as a
subsidy for providers that have been
unable to attract users, the Commission
believes that this approach recognizes
the still unbalanced structure of the VRS
industry, as well as the incompleteness
of VRS reforms intended to enhance
competition. In light of the apparently
fragile current state of VRS competition
and the per-minute cost differentials,
the Commission concludes it would be
unwise at this time to subject two of the
current four competitors to the dramatic
rate reductions that would be necessary
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:39 Aug 21, 2017
Jkt 241001
to fit them under the same tiered rate
structure as the other two, much larger
providers. Further, smaller providers
may offer service features that are
designed for niche VRS market
segments or that may not be available
through other providers and that are
helpful in meeting the specific needs of
particular VRS consumers. By providing
an emergent rate, the Commission can
increase the likelihood that, in the near
term, even if no new entrants arrive,
consumers can continue to select a
service provider from four competitors
instead of two.
33. In order to maintain incentives for
growth and avoid subjecting emergent
providers to a sudden drop in the rate
applicable to all their minutes when
they reach the 500,000-minute ceiling,
providers who are initially subject to the
emergent rate and who then generate
monthly minutes exceeding 500,000
shall continue to be compensated at the
otherwise applicable emergent rate
(rather than the Tier I rate) for their first
500,000 monthly minutes, until the end
of the four-year rate plan, i.e., until June
30, 2021. Such providers shall be
compensated at the otherwise
applicable Tier I rate for monthly
minutes between 500,000 and 1 million.
34. For emergent providers, the
Commission adopts a $5.29 per minute
rate for each year of the four-year plan.
To the extent that these providers have
demonstrated the ability to show
consistent, substantial growth over the
past years, provider cost projections
indicate that this rate will afford such
providers a reasonable opportunity to
meet their expenses and earn some
profit. The Commission expects that this
opportunity should be enhanced with
the implementation of provider
interoperability and other competitionpromoting measures, such as the
development and publication of service
quality metrics.
35. However, the Commission does
not intend that this rate structure
continue to apply to any currently
operating providers after the end of the
four-year rate plan adopted in document
FCC 17–86. During the next four years,
the provision of a special rate for
emergent providers may not impose
major costs on Fund contributors, but
the likely benefits to consumers will
also remain very limited unless these
emergent companies manage to use this
four-year window of opportunity to
expand their market share. Therefore,
after four years, the Commission intends
that all existing providers, regardless of
size, will be subject to the same rate
structure (whether tiered or unitary)
under the compensation scheme that
then takes effect.
PO 00000
Frm 00024
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
36. Tiers I–III. The Commission also
adopts the proposed tier structure, in
which a provider’s monthly minutes up
to 1,000,000 will be included in Tier I,
monthly minutes between 1,000,001
and 2,500,000 in Tier II, and all monthly
minutes above 2,500,000 in Tier III,
with the highest rate applicable to Tier
I minutes and the lowest rate applicable
to Tier III minutes. Based on real-world
evidence, which consistently shows the
existence of substantial disparities
among the per-minute costs incurred by
VRS providers, which are broadly inline with the similarly wide disparities
in their volumes of minutes, the
Commission concludes that there are
likely to be substantial economies of
scale in administrative costs, marketing,
and other areas.
37. Further, the existence of persistent
cost differences between the largest and
lowest-cost VRS provider and its
smaller competitors is undisputed. To
maintain a competitive environment for
the near term, the Commission’s most
realistic option is to set compensation
rates that allow the few remaining VRS
competitors an additional period of time
to offer a competitive alternative to the
lowest-cost provider, while reforms
continue to be implemented. In this
context, the Commission’s primary
concern is not to identify the exact
extent of scale economies but to ensure
that tiers reflect the disparate sizes and
cost structures of current competitors.
Further, as the Commission also
recognized in 2013, significant potential
harm to competition could result if the
rate tier boundaries are too low and
prevent smaller competitors from
remaining in the market, while if the
Commission sets the boundaries too
high the only consequence will be that
smaller, less efficient competitors may
remain in the market longer than would
otherwise be the case, resulting in
somewhat higher expenditures from the
Fund. With the intervening attrition in
the number of VRS competitors, the
Commission’s preference is even greater
today for striking a balance that
emphasizes preserving competition.
38. The Commission expands the Tier
I boundary to 1,000,000 minutes, in
order to ensure that the ‘‘emergent’’
providers, as well as any new entrants,
as they grow large enough to leave the
‘‘emergent’’ category, will be subject to
a rate that reflects their size and likely
cost structure and that is appropriately
higher than the marginal rate applicable
to larger and more efficient providers.
Tier I, which also applies to the first
1,000,000 minutes of each larger
provider, allows the Commission to set
a rate that is high enough to ensure that
each provider is able to cover its
E:\FR\FM\22AUR1.SGM
22AUR1
sradovich on DSK3GMQ082PROD with RULES
Federal Register / Vol. 82, No. 161 / Tuesday, August 22, 2017 / Rules and Regulations
relatively fixed, less variable costs. The
Commission expands the Tier II
boundary, as well, to 2,500,000 minutes,
for similar reasons. Expanding the Tier
II boundaries, which applies to the
minutes of all providers in excess of the
1,000,000-minutes threshold and up to
the 2,500,000-minutes ceiling, enables
the Commission to set a rate that is
appropriately lower than the Tier I rate,
but higher than the rate for Tier III,
which will currently apply only to the
largest provider, whose per-minute costs
are far lower than any other provider’s.
The Tier II rate can thus be set low
enough to ensure that providers with
more than 1,000,000 minutes are not
compensated far in excess of their
allowable costs, but high enough to
ensure that such providers have an
incentive to continue providing
additional minutes of service. By
increasing the upper boundary of this
tier, as well as Tier I, the Commission
also limits any risk of eroding a
provider’s incentive to continue
growing as its monthly minutes
approach a tier boundary. The lower
Tier III rate, in turn, will appropriately
be the marginal rate for the largest,
lowest-cost provider.
39. Application of rate tiers to
commonly owned providers. Regarding
the recent merger of two VRS providers,
Purple Communications, Inc. (Purple),
and CSDVRS, LLC d/b/a ZVRS (ZVRS),
there is disagreement among the
commenters as to whether the
compensation rate tiers should apply to
these now-affiliated companies
separately or on a consolidated basis,
prior to their full consolidation. The
VRS compensation system should be
designed, as far as possible, to avoid
creating undesirable incentives to
exploit the tier structure by creating
multiple subsidiaries for the provision
of VRS. However, the consent decree
that authorized the merger between
ZVRS and Purple specifically includes
language providing that the two entities
will continue to operate and submit
requests for compensation payments as
separate VRS providers, and will be
treated as separate entities for
compliance purposes, for up to 36
months after the effective date (i.e., until
February 15, 2020), after which they
will consolidate the operations of the
two VRS providers. As applied here,
that determination means that the two
companies will be treated as separate
entities for purposes of the tiered rate
structure until February 14, 2020, or
until such time that these companies
consolidate their operations. After
February 14, 2020, or from the date of
consolidation if it takes place earlier,
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:39 Aug 21, 2017
Jkt 241001
these companies will be treated as a
single provider for purposes of the
tiered rate compensation structure. To
ensure compliance with this outcome,
the Commission directs ZVRS to
provide the Commission with 60 days
notice prior to such consolidation.
40. Rate period and adjustments. As
with the prior rate plan, the new rate
plan will be four years in duration. A
four-year period is long enough to offer
a substantial degree of rate stability,
thereby (1) giving providers certainty
regarding the future applicable rate; (2)
providing a significant incentive for
providers to become more efficient
without incurring a penalty; and (3)
mitigating any risk of creating the
‘‘rolling average’’ problem previously
identified by the Commission regarding
TRS, in which the use of rates based on
averaged provider costs, if recalculated
every year, could leave some providers
without adequate compensation, even if
they are reasonably efficient. On the
other hand, a four-year period is short
enough to allow an opportunity for the
Commission to reset the rates in
response to substantial cost changes or
other significant developments that may
occur over time. Given the lack of
support for continuing six-month
adjustments, the Commission adopts the
administratively simpler approach of
having rate adjustments occur annually
over the next four-year rate period.
41. Rate Levels. In setting rate levels,
the Commission seeks to limit the
likelihood that any provider’s total
compensation will be insufficient to
provide a reasonable margin over its
allowable expenses, and to limit the
extent of any overcompensation of a
provider in relation to its allowable
expenses and reasonable operating
margin. Further, the Commission seeks
to avoid any risk of setting a rate for any
tier that is either below the marginal
cost of a provider subject to that tier or
excessively above such marginal cost.
42. Tier I Rate Level. For this tier, the
FNPRM sought comment on a range of
possible rates—from $4.06 to $4.82 for
the first year and from $3.74 to $4.82 for
the fourth year. The current rate level of
$4.06 per minute (in conjunction with
the $3.49 rate currently applicable to a
provider’s minutes in excess of 1
million)—is too low to permit all
providers to meet their allowable
expenses and earn a reasonable
operating margin. Instead, the
Commission adopts the rate of $4.82 per
minute recommended by the nondominant providers, which will apply
to all four years of the rate period. A
Tier I rate at this level will allow all
providers subject to it to recover their
allowable expenses and earn an
PO 00000
Frm 00025
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
39679
operating margin within the zone of
reasonableness. This Tier I rate level
also provides an appropriate incentive
for emergent providers to grow their
businesses beyond 500,000 minutes.
43. Tier II. The Commission adopts a
Tier II rate of $3.97 per minute for all
four years of the rate period. For this
tier, the FNPRM sought comment on a
range of possible rates—from $3.49 to
$4.35 for the first year and from $3.08
to $4.35 for the fourth year. The $3.97
rate the Commission adopts is roughly
in the middle of the range of Tier II
options for the first year. The $4.35 per
minute rate advocated by the nondominant providers is higher than is
necessary to allow providers to recover
their allowable costs and earn a
reasonable operating margin. On the
other hand, the current rate level of
$3.49, combined with the current Tier I
level, is too low to permit all providers
to earn a reasonable operating margin.
Based on the data reported by providers,
applying the $3.97 rate for all four years
of the rate period, in conjunction with
other applicable rates, will allow all
providers subject to this rate to recover
their allowable expenses and earn an
operating margin within the zone of
reasonableness the Commission has
adopted. At $3.97, this rate is also above
the allowable expenses per minute of
any provider subject to the Tier II rate,
thus minimizing the risk of deterring
such a provider from increasing its VRS
minutes. At the same time, the Tier II
rate is at a level that, in conjunction
with other applicable rates, limits any
overcompensation of providers subject
to it.
44. Tier III. For this tier, the FNPRM
sought comment on a range of possible
rates—from $2.83 to $3.49 for the first
year and from $2.63 to $3.49 for the
fourth year. The Commission concludes
that the rate level for Tier III should be
$3.21 in the first year and $2.63 per
minute in the final year. The $2.63 rate
is higher than the average allowable
expenses per minute for the current
provider subject to this tier, and, in
conjunction with other applicable rates,
will allow providers that fall into this
tier to earn an operating margin over
allowable expenses that is within the
zone of reasonableness the Commission
has adopted. However, because this rate
is a substantial reduction from the
current Tier III rate, a gradual transition
to reach this rate level is appropriate.
Accordingly, the Commission adopts a
rate of $3.21 per minute for Fund Year
2017–18, the first year of the rate plan
period. This continues the ongoing
adjustment of the Tier III rate, under the
previous rate plan, under which it
dropped by $.38 per minute per year, as
E:\FR\FM\22AUR1.SGM
22AUR1
39680
Federal Register / Vol. 82, No. 161 / Tuesday, August 22, 2017 / Rules and Regulations
sradovich on DSK3GMQ082PROD with RULES
the initial rate of $3.21 is $.38 below the
approximate average ($3.59) of the $3.68
and $3.49 Tier III rates applicable
during the 2016–17 Fund Year. The Tier
III rate will be reduced by another $0.38
in Fund Year 2018–19, to a rate of $2.83
per minute. For the final two years, the
Tier III rate will be $2.63 per minute.
45. Although Sorenson asserts that a
proper analysis of VRS costs indicates
the Tier III rate should be higher, the
Commission does not rely on Sorenson’s
analysis for several reasons. First,
projections for the second year out (in
this case, 2018), which are included in
Sorenson’s analysis, historically have
had a poor record of accuracy. Second,
Sorenson’s cost calculation includes
costs that are not allowable, as well as
a 15.9% operating margin, which is
outside the zone of reasonableness the
Commission has adopted.
46. Aggregate effect of the rate levels
adopted. The approach adopted here
effectively balances the Commission’s
overarching goal of maintaining
competition and consumer choice with
its obligation to administer the Fund in
an efficient manner. When aggregated, if
the tiered compensation rates currently
in effect were to be extended for four
more years, assuming the present
growth of this service, compensation
payments from the TRS Fund to VRS
providers would be expected to total
(over these four years) approximately
$1,887,000,000. This figure would swell
to approximately $1,925,000,000, were
the Commission to adopt the single-rate
approach proposed by Sorenson at the
lowest rate that Sorenson deems
acceptable—$3.73 per minute. This
would not only result in an increase of
about $38 million over extending the
current rates, but also would stifle
competition in the VRS market by likely
eliminating all but one provider. By
contrast, under the tiered rate plan
adopted today, the Commission expects
that the total cost to the TRS Fund will
be approximately $1,835,000,000, which
will produce a cost savings of
approximately $52 million compared to
current rates and preserve the
competitive VRS environment that
consumers now enjoy.
Other Compensation Matters
47. Audits for providers receiving the
emergent rate. The existing, more
generally applicable rules regarding
audits are sufficient to address any
accuracy issues regarding emergent
providers’ costs. Therefore, the
Commission declines to adopt a
separate, mandatory audit requirement
for providers receiving the emergent
rate. However, the Commission reminds
all current and potential VRS providers
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:39 Aug 21, 2017
Jkt 241001
that their costs may be subject to audit
at any time to assure the accuracy and
integrity of TRS Fund compensation
rates and payments.
48. Exogenous costs. In general, the
2007 model for exogenous cost recovery
is procedurally sufficient for addressing
provider requests for compensation for
exogenous costs. Substantively, given
that the tiered rates set in document
FCC 17–86 are intended to reduce VRS
compensation rates in the direction of
cost-based levels that have yet to be
reached, the Commission adopts the
following conditions to ensure that
exogenous cost recovery does not result
in increasing the disparity between
Fund expenditures and actual provider
costs. Providers may seek compensation
for well-documented exogenous costs
that (1) belong to a category of costs that
the Commission has deemed allowable,
(2) result from new TRS service
requirements or other causes beyond the
provider’s control, (3) are new costs that
were not factored into the applicable
compensation rates, and (4) if
unrecovered, would cause a provider’s
current allowable-expenses-plusoperating margin to exceed its VRS
revenues.
49. Effective date. VRS compensation
rates historically have been set
prospectively and are normally not
adjusted retrospectively unless an error
has been made. In establishing the rates
applicable to the current period, the
Commission acted appropriately based
on the record, and the Commission is
not aware of any compelling reason to
reconsider those ratemaking decisions.
Further, while the Commission found it
necessary in 2016 to retrospectively
apply an emergency rate freeze with
respect to the smallest VRS providers,
the Commission does not find that a
comparable emergency exists now
necessitating further adjustment of rates
for the same period for which they were
already adjusted once on an emergency
basis. Accordingly, the Commission
declines to give the new rates
retrospective effect back to January 1,
2017; rather, the rates the Commission
adopts are effective as of July 1, 2017.
50. The Commission finds good cause
to make the rule changes adopting a
new four-year rate plan in document
FCC 17–86 effective as of July 1, 2017.
The current rate plan was scheduled to
expire on June 30, 2017. Providers have
been aware of this pending expiration
since 2013, and have further been aware
of the Commission’s proposal to
establish a new rate plan going forward.
To avoid unnecessary disruption to VRS
providers’ operations and to ensure the
ability of consumers to continue to
place and receive VRS calls, the
PO 00000
Frm 00026
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
Consumer and Governmental Affairs
Bureau (Bureau) recently acted to waive
the June 30, 2017 expiration of the
existing rates and directed Rolka Loube
to continue compensating VRS
providers at the prevailing rates,
pending further action by the
Commission.
51. As the Commission now takes
action to establish a new four-year rate
regime, the Commission directs Rolka
Loube to compensate VRS providers at
the applicable rates adopted herein for
all compensable minutes of use incurred
beginning July 1, 2017, except that, to
ensure that the release of document FCC
17–86 after July 1 does not adversely
affect any VRS provider, the
Commission will not apply the
reduction in Tier III rates to any
compensable minutes of use incurred
between July 1 and the release date of
document FCC 17–86. To implement
this provision (given that minutes of use
are compensated on a monthly basis),
the Commission directs Rolka Loube to
compensate any provider with Tier III
minutes in July 2017 at a rate of $3.49
per minute for the first X Tier III
minutes, where X equals the number of
compensable minutes of use incurred
between July 1 and the release of
document FCC 17–86. So if a VRS
provider has no Tier III minutes in July
2017, this provision will not affect it; if
a provider has X or fewer Tier III
minutes, then all such minutes will be
compensated at the higher $3.49 rate;
and if a provider has more than X Tier
III minutes, then it will receive $3.49
per minute for the first X Tier III
minutes and $3.21 for all remaining Tier
III minutes. The Commission also
directs the Bureau to provide actual
notice to known VRS providers by
sending them a copy of document FCC
17–86.
52. Historical Cost vs. Projected Costs.
For purposes of document FCC 17–86,
a review of the past relationships
between projected and actual costs
indicates that the most reliable reference
points for cost calculations when rates
are set are the actual costs reported for
the previous calendar year and the
projected costs for the current calendar
year. The least reliable reference point
is the projected costs for the year after
the current year. Accordingly, as a
reference point for cost calculations for
purposes of document FCC 17–86, the
Commission uses the weighted average
of each provider’s actual costs and
demand for 2016 and projected costs
and demand for 2017.
Other Matters—Server-Based Routing
53. Under the TRS numbering rules,
calls that involve multiple VRS
E:\FR\FM\22AUR1.SGM
22AUR1
Federal Register / Vol. 82, No. 161 / Tuesday, August 22, 2017 / Rules and Regulations
providers are routed based on the
information provided in the TRS
Numbering Directory. Section 64.613(a)
of the Commission’s rules currently
requires that the Uniform Resource
Identifier (URI) for a VRS user’s
telephone number contain the IP
address of the user’s device. However,
the VRS Provider Interoperability
Profile technical standard provides for
the routing of inter-provider VRS and
point-to-point video calls to a server of
the terminating VRS provider rather
than directly to a specific device. The
technical standard thus specifies the use
of call routing information that contains
provider domain names, rather than
user-specific IP addresses. To permit the
implementation of the VRS Provider
Interoperability Profile, which has been
incorporated by reference into the
Commission’s rules, it is necessary to
amend the TRS Numbering Directory
rule. This change will foster the
implementation of interoperability,
thereby enhancing functional
equivalence. In addition, allowing
routing based on domain names will
promote TRS regulation that
‘‘encourage[s] . . . the use of existing
technology and do[es] not discourage or
impair the development of improved
technology,’’ as required by 47 U.S.C.
225(c)(2), and will improve the
efficiency, reliability, and security of
VRS and point-to-point video
communications, thus advancing these
important Commission objectives as
well. The Commission also finds that
server-based routing will not impair the
Commission’s ability to prevent waste,
fraud, and abuse in the VRS program.
sradovich on DSK3GMQ082PROD with RULES
Other Matters—Research and
Development
54. The Commission adopts its
proposal in the FNPRM to direct the
TRS Fund administrator, as part of
annual ratemaking proceedings, to
include in the proposed TRS Fund
administrative budget an appropriate
amount for Commission-directed
research and development R&D. These
funds will enable the Commission to
ensure that TRS evolves with
improvements in technology. Because
the TRS Fund administrator previously
submitted its recommended budget for
the 2017–18 Fund Year without
recommending a specific amount for
R&D, the Commission also allocates $6.1
million from the TRS Fund to be used
for R&D projects to be overseen by the
Commission in the 2017–18 TRS Fund
Year.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:39 Aug 21, 2017
Jkt 241001
Other Matters—Repeal of the Neutral
Video Communications Service
Platform
55. The Commission adopts its
proposal to delete the rule provisions
relating to the neutral video
communications service platform
(Neutral VRS Platform). Although the
Commission requested bids to build the
Neutral VRS Platform, no acceptable
bids were received, and the Commission
canceled that procurement. Because no
party has made any showing that the
Commission should request new bids
for the Neutral VRS Platform or
otherwise expressed any interest in
utilizing it, the Commission (i) removes
§§ 64.601(a)(20) and (45), 64.611(h), and
64.617 and (ii) modifies
§§ 64.604(b)(2)(iii), (b)(4)(iv), and
(c)(5)(iii)(N)(1)(iii) and 64.606(a)(4) of
the Commission’s rules to eliminate
references to the Neutral VRS Platform
and VRS communications assistant (CA)
service providers (the entities that
would have made use of the platform).
39681
providers employ server-based routing,
and the existing Commission rule,
under which they must route calls based
on the IP address of the user’s device.
Now that the Commission, in document
FCC 17–86, has amended 47 CFR
64.613(a)(2) to permit server-based
routing, the Commission reestablishes
the effectiveness of the rule amendment
incorporating the VRS Provider
Interoperability Profile, adopted in the
Report and Order (2017 VRS
Interoperability Order), DA 17–76,
published at 82 FR 19322, April 27,
2017.
Other Matters—Technical Correction to
the VRS Speed-of-Answer Rule
Final Regulatory Flexibility Analysis
58. As required by the Regulatory
Flexibility Act of 1980 (RFA), as
amended, the Commission incorporated
an Initial Regulatory Flexibility
Analysis (IRFA) into the FNPRM. The
Commission sought written public
comment on its proposals in the
FNPRM, including comment on the
IRFA. No comments were received on
the IRFA. This Final Regulatory
Flexibility Analysis (FRFA) conforms to
the RFA.
56. In the 2013 VRS Reform Order, the
Commission modified § 64.604(b)(2)(iii)
of the Commission’s rules, the speed-ofanswer rule, changing it from (a) a
requirement to answer 80% of all VRS
calls within 120 seconds, measured on
a monthly basis, to (b) a requirement to
answer 85% of all VRS calls (i) within
60 seconds, measured on a daily basis,
by January 1, 2014, and (ii) within 30
seconds, measured on a daily basis, by
July 1, 2014. The United States Court of
Appeals for the District of Columbia
Circuit (D.C. Circuit) vacated this aspect
of the 2013 VRS Reform Order. The
court ruled that, pending further action
by the Commission, its decision ‘‘will
have the effect of reinstating the
requirement that 80% of VRS calls be
answered within 120 seconds, measured
on a monthly basis.’’ The Commission
therefore amends § 64.604(b)(2)(iii) of its
rules to comply with the mandate of the
D.C. Circuit and provide for a speed-ofanswer requirement to answer 80% of
all VRS calls within 120 seconds,
measured on a monthly basis.
Need for, and Objectives of, the
Proposed Rules
59. Document FCC 17–86 addresses
server-based routing of VRS calls, and
funding for Commission-directed R&D.
60. First, by amending TRS rules to
permit server-based routing, document
FCC 17–86 expands the ways that VRS
calls can be routed. Under a new
interoperability standard, calls may be
routed to a server of the terminating
VRS provider that serves multiple VRS
users and devices, rather than directly
to a specific device. This new routing
method uses the providers’ domain
names, rather than user-specific IP
addresses, as is currently required.
61. Second, the Commission directs
the TRS Fund administrator, as part of
future annual ratemaking proceedings,
to include for Commission approval
proposed funding for Commissiondirected R&D. Such funding is necessary
to continue to meet the Commission’s
charge of furthering the goals of
functional equivalence and efficient
availability of TRS.
Order
Summary of Significant Issues Raised by
Public Comments in Response to the
IRFA
62. No comments were filed in
response to the IRFA.
57. In the Order (2017 VRS
Improvements Order), FCC 17–26,
published at 82 FR 28566, June 23,
2017, the Commission set aside the
effectiveness of the VRS Provider
Interoperability Profile technical
standard until the Commission resolved
the apparent conflict between the VRS
Provider Interoperability Profile
technical standard, under which VRS
PO 00000
Frm 00027
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
Small Entities Impacted
63. The server-based routing rule
amendment adopted in document FCC
17–86 will affect obligations of VRS
Providers. These services can be
E:\FR\FM\22AUR1.SGM
22AUR1
39682
Federal Register / Vol. 82, No. 161 / Tuesday, August 22, 2017 / Rules and Regulations
included within the broad economic
category of All Other
Telecommunications. Five providers
currently receive compensation from the
TRS Fund for providing VRS: ASL
Services Holdings, LLC; CSDVRS, LLC;
Convo Communications, LLC; Purple
Communications, Inc.; and Sorenson
Communications, Inc. The R&D funding
will have no impact on VRS providers.
Description of Projected Reporting,
Recordkeeping, and Other Compliance
Requirements
64. Server-based call routing involves
the use of domain names, and VRS
providers using this method will need
to keep records of such domain names.
The domain names will then be
processed as call routing information,
just as other call routing information is
processed currently. The funding for
R&D will have no reporting,
recordkeeping, or other compliance
requirements.
Steps Taken To Minimize Significant
Impact on Small Entities, and
Significant Alternatives Considered
65. Server-based call routing using
domain names will be available to all
VRS providers, will not be burdensome,
and will advance interoperability.
Greater interoperability will foster
competition, thereby benefitting the
smaller providers. To the extent there
are differences in operating costs
resulting from economies of scale, those
costs are reflected in the different
compensation rate structures applicable
to large and small VRS providers.
66. The funding for R&D does not
have any compliance or reporting
requirements impacting small entities.
Indeed, small entities are not covered by
the rule.
67. No commenters raised other
alternatives that would lessen the
impact of any of these requirements on
`
small entities vis-a-vis larger entities.
sradovich on DSK3GMQ082PROD with RULES
Federal Rules Which Duplicate,
Overlap, or Conflict With, the
Commission’s Proposals
68. None.
Ordering Clauses
69. Pursuant to sections 1, 2, and 225
of the Communications Act of 1934, as
amended, 47 U.S.C. 151, 152, and 225,
document FCC 17–86 is adopted, and
part 64 of Title 47 is amended.
70. Pursuant to section 553(d)(3) of
the Administrative Procedure Act, 5
U.S.C. 553(d)(3), and §§ 1.4(b)(1) and
1.427(b) of the Commission’s rules, 47
CFR 1.4(b)(1), 1.427(b), the VRS
compensation rates became effective on
July 1, 2017.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:39 Aug 21, 2017
Jkt 241001
71. A copy of document FCC 17–86
shall be sent by overnight mail, first
class mail and certified mail, return
receipt requested, to all known VRS
providers.
72. The Commission’s Consumer and
Governmental Affairs Bureau, Reference
Information Center, shall send a copy of
document FCC 17–86, including the
Final Regulatory Flexibility Analysis, to
the Chief Counsel for Advocacy of the
Small Business Administration.
List of Subjects in 47 CFR Part 64
Incorporation by reference,
Individuals with disabilities,
Telecommunications relay services,
Video relay services.
Federal Communications Commission.
Marlene H. Dortch,
Secretary.
Final Rules
For the reasons discussed in the
preamble, the Federal Communications
Commission amends 47 CFR part 64 as
follows:
PART 64—MISCELLANEOUS RULES
RELATING TO COMMON CARRIERS
1. The authority citation for part 64
continues to read as follows:
■
Authority: 47 U.S.C. 154, 225, 254(k),
403(b)(2)(B), (c), 715, Pub. L. 104–104, 110
Stat. 56. Interpret or apply 47 U.S.C. 201,
218, 222, 225, 226, 227, 228, 254(k), 616, 620,
and the Middle Class Tax Relief and Job
Creation Act of 2012, Pub. L. 112–96, unless
otherwise noted.
2. Amend § 64.601 by:
a. Revising paragraph (a)(12);
b. Removing paragraph (a)(20);
c. Redesignating paragraphs (a)(14)
through (19) as paragraphs (a)(15)
through (20) and adding new paragraph
(a)(14);
■ d. Revising paragraph (a)(26);
■ e. Removing paragraphs (a)(45)
through (49);
■ f. Redesignating paragraphs (a)(27)
through (44) as paragraphs (a)(30)
through (47) and adding new paragraphs
(a)(27) through (29); and
■ g. Revising newly redesignated
paragraph (a)(30).
The additions and revisions read as
follows:
■
■
■
■
§ 64.601 Definitions and provisions of
general applicability.
(a) * * *
(12) Default provider change order. A
request by an iTRS user to an iTRS
provider to change the user’s default
provider.
*
*
*
*
*
(14) Hearing point-to-point video user.
A hearing individual who has been
PO 00000
Frm 00028
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
assigned a ten-digit NANP number that
is entered in the TRS Numbering
Directory to access point-to-point
service.
*
*
*
*
*
(26) Point-to-point video call. A call
placed via a point-to-point video
service.
(27) Point-to-point video service. A
service that enables a user to place and
receive non-relay video calls without
the assistance of a CA.
(28) Qualified interpreter. An
interpreter who is able to interpret
effectively, accurately, and impartially,
both receptively and expressively, using
any necessary specialized vocabulary.
(29) Real-Time Text (RTT). The term
real-time text shall have the meaning set
forth in § 67.1 of this chapter.
(30) Registered Internet-based TRS
user. An individual that has registered
with a VRS or IP Relay provider as
described in § 64.611.
*
*
*
*
*
■ 3. Amend § 64.604 by revising
paragraphs (b)(2)(iii), (b)(4)(iv), and
(c)(5)(iii)(N)(1)(iii) to read as follows:
§ 64.604
Mandatory minimum standards.
*
*
*
*
*
(b) * * *
(2) * * *
(iii) Speed of answer requirements for
VRS providers. VRS providers must
answer 80% of all VRS calls within 120
seconds, measured on a monthly basis.
VRS providers must meet the speed of
answer requirements for VRS providers
as measured from the time a VRS call
reaches facilities operated by the VRS
provider to the time when the call is
answered by a CA—i.e., not when the
call is put on hold, placed in a queue,
or connected to an IVR system.
Abandoned calls shall be included in
the VRS speed of answer calculation.
*
*
*
*
*
(4) * * *
(iv) A VRS provider leasing or
licensing an automatic call distribution
(ACD) platform must have a written
lease or license agreement. Such lease or
license agreement may not include any
revenue sharing agreement or
compensation based upon minutes of
use. In addition, if any such lease is
between two eligible VRS providers, the
lessee or licensee must locate the ACD
platform on its own premises and must
utilize its own employees to manage the
ACD platform.
*
*
*
*
*
(c) * * *
(5) * * *
(iii) * * *
(N) * * *
(1) * * *
E:\FR\FM\22AUR1.SGM
22AUR1
Federal Register / Vol. 82, No. 161 / Tuesday, August 22, 2017 / Rules and Regulations
(iii) An eligible VRS provider may not
contract with or otherwise authorize any
third party to provide interpretation
services or call center functions
(including call distribution, call routing,
call setup, mapping, call features,
billing, and registration) on its behalf,
unless that authorized third party also is
an eligible provider.
*
*
*
*
*
§ 64.606
[Amended]
4. Amend § 64.606 by removing
paragraph (a)(4).
■
§ 64.611
[Amended]
5. Amend § 64.611 by removing
paragraph (h).
■ 6. Amend § 64.613 by revising
paragraph (a)(2) to read as follows:
■
§ 64.613 Numbering directory for Internetbased TRS users.
(a) * * *
(2) For each record associated with a
VRS user’s geographically appropriate
NANP telephone number, the URI shall
contain a server domain name or the IP
address of the user’s device. For each
record associated with an IP Relay
user’s geographically appropriate NANP
telephone number, the URI shall contain
the user’s user name and domain name
that can be subsequently resolved to
reach the user.
*
*
*
*
*
§ 64.617
[Removed]
7. Remove § 64.617.
8. Amend § 64.621 by revising
paragraph (b)(1) to read as follows:
■
■
§ 64.621
Interoperability and portability.
*
*
*
*
*
(b) * * *
(1) Beginning no later than December
20, 2017, VRS providers shall ensure
that their provision of VRS and video
communications, including their access
technology, meets the requirements of
the VRS Provider Interoperability
Profile.
*
*
*
*
*
[FR Doc. 2017–17225 Filed 8–21–17; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6712–01–P
FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS
COMMISSION
sradovich on DSK3GMQ082PROD with RULES
47 CFR Part 96
[GN Docket No. 12–354; FCC 15–47]
Final rule; announcement of
effective date.
ACTION:
In this document, the Federal
Communications Commission
(Commission) announces that the Office
of Management and Budget (OMB) has
approved, via a non-substantive change
request, the information collection
requirements associated with
Commercial Operations in the 3550–
3650 MHz Band adopted in the
Commission’s First Report and Order,
GN Docket No. 12–354, FCC 15–47. This
document is consistent with the First
Report and Order, which stated that the
Commission would publish a document
in the Federal Register announcing
OMB approval and the effective date of
the requirements.
DATES: 47 CFR 96.49, published at 80 FR
36163, June 23, 2015, is effective on
August 22, 2017.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: For
additional information, contact Cathy
Williams, Cathy.Williams@fcc.gov, (202)
418–2918.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: This
document announces that, on August 7,
2015, OMB approved, via a nonsubstantive change request, the
information collection requirements
associated with two technical rules (47
CFR 96.49 and 96.51) adopted in the
Commission’s First Report and Order,
FCC 15–47, published at 80 FR 36163,
June 23, 2015. The OMB Control
Number is 3060–0057. The Commission
publishes this document as an
announcement of the effective date of
the requirements. If you have any
comments on the burden estimates
listed below, or how the Commission
can improve the collections and reduce
any burdens caused thereby, please
contact Cathy Williams, Federal
Communications Commission, Room 1–
C823, 445 12th Street SW., Washington,
DC 20554. Please include the OMB
Control Number 3060–0057 in your
correspondence. The Commission will
also accept your comments via email at
PRA@fcc.gov.
To request materials in accessible
formats for people with disabilities
(Braille, large print, electronic files,
audio format), send an email to fcc504@
fcc.gov or call the Consumer and
Governmental Affairs Bureau at (202)
418–0530 (voice), (202) 418–0432
(TTY).
SUMMARY:
Synopsis
Amendment of the Commission’s
Rules With Regard to Commercial
Operations in the 3550–3650 MHz Band
Federal Communications
Commission.
AGENCY:
VerDate Sep<11>2014
16:39 Aug 21, 2017
Jkt 241001
As required by the Paperwork
Reduction Act of 1995 (44 U.S.C. 3507),
the FCC is notifying the public that it
received OMB approval on August 7,
2015, for the non-substantive change to
PO 00000
Frm 00029
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
39683
information collection requirements
contained in the Commission’s rules at
47 CFR 96.49 and 96.51. Under 5 CFR
part 1320, an agency may not conduct
or sponsor a collection of information
unless it displays a current, valid OMB
Control Number.
No person shall be subject to any
penalty for failing to comply with a
collection of information subject to the
Paperwork Reduction Act that does not
display a current, valid OMB Control
Number. The OMB Control Numbers is
3060–0057.
The foregoing notice is required by
the Paperwork Reduction Act of 1995,
Public Law 104–13, October 1, 1995,
and 44 U.S.C. 3507.
The total annual reporting burdens
and costs for the respondents are as
follows:
OMB Control Number: 3060–0057.
OMB Approval Date: August 7, 2015.
OMB Expiration Date: May 31, 2020.
Title: Application for Equipment
Authorization, FCC Form 731.
Form Number: FCC Form 731.
Respondents: Business or other forprofit entities and state, local or tribal
government.
Number of Respondents and
Responses: 3,740 respondents and
22,250.
Estimated Time per Response: 35
hours.
Frequency of Response: On occasion
reporting requirement and third party
disclosure requirement.
Obligation to Respond: Required to
obtain or retain benefits. The statutory
authority for this collection is contained
in 47 U.S.C. 154(i), 301, 302, 303(e),
303(f) and 303(r).
Total Annual Burden: 778,750.
Annual Cost Burden: No cost.
Privacy Act Impact Assessment: No
impact(s).
Nature and Extent of Confidentiality:
There is no need for confidentiality with
this collection of information.
Needs and Uses: The FCC adopted a
First Report and Order, FCC 15–47, for
commercial use of 150 megahertz in the
3550–3700 MHz (3.5 GHz) band and a
new Citizens Broadband Radio Service,
published at 80 FR 36163, June 23,
2015. 3.5 GHz Band users will use
Citizens Broadband Radio Service
Devices (CBSDs) to operate, which are
fixed stations, or networks of such
stations that fall under two categories,
Category A CBSDs, which operate at
lower power, or Category B that operate
at a higher power. The rules require
compliance with information
requirements contained in the First
Report and Order already accounted for
and approved under this Office of
Management and Budget (OMB) control
E:\FR\FM\22AUR1.SGM
22AUR1
Agencies
[Federal Register Volume 82, Number 161 (Tuesday, August 22, 2017)]
[Rules and Regulations]
[Pages 39673-39683]
From the Federal Register Online via the Government Publishing Office [www.gpo.gov]
[FR Doc No: 2017-17225]
=======================================================================
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION
47 CFR Part 64
[CG Docket Nos. 10-51 and 03-123; FCC 17-86]
Structure and Practices of the Video Relay Services Program
AGENCY: Federal Communications Commission.
ACTION: Final rule.
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
SUMMARY: In this document, the Commission adopts a four-year rate plan
to compensate video relay service (VRS) providers, amends its rules to
permit-server based routing for VRS and point-to-point calls,
authorizes the continued use of money from the Telecommunications Relay
Service (TRS) Fund for Commission-supervised research and development,
eliminates rules providing for a neutral video communications service
platform, and reinstates the effectiveness of the rule incorporating
the VRS Interoperability Profile technical standard.
DATES: Effective September 21, 2017. The compliance date for 47 CFR
64.621(b)(1) is December 20, 2017. The incorporation by reference of
certain publication listed in the rules was approved by the Director of
the Federal Register as of May 30, 2017.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: Bob Aldrich, Consumer and Governmental
Affairs Bureau at: (202) 418-0996, email Robert.Aldrich@fcc.gov, or
Eliot Greenwald, Consumer and Governmental Affairs Bureau at: (202)
418-2235, email Eliot.Greenwald@fcc.gov.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: This is a summary of the Commission's Report
and Order and Order, FCC 17-86, adopted and released on July 6, 2017,
in CG Docket Nos. 10-51 and 03-123. The full text of this document will
be available for public inspection and copying via the Commission's
Electronic Comment Filing System (ECFS), and during regular business
hours at the FCC Reference Information Center, Portals II, 445 12th
Street SW., Room CY-A257, Washington, DC 20554. To request materials in
accessible formats for people with disabilities (Braille, large print,
electronic files, audio format), send an email to fcc504@fcc.gov or
call the Consumer and Governmental Affairs Bureau at (202) 418-0530
(voice), (844) 432-2272 (videophone), or (202) 418-0432 (TTY).
Congressional Review Act
The Commission sent a copy of document FCC 17-86 to Congress and
the Government Accountability Office pursuant to the Congressional
Review Act, see 5 U.S.C. 801(a)(1)(A).
Final Paperwork Reduction Act of 1995 Analysis
Document FCC 17-86 does not contain any new or modified information
collection requirements subject to the Paperwork Reduction Act of 1995,
Pub. L. 104-13. In addition, therefore, it does not contain any new or
modified information collection burden for small business concerns with
fewer than 25 employees, pursuant to the Small Business Paperwork
Relief Act of 2002, Pub. L. 107-198, see 44 U.S.C. 3506(c)(4).
Synopsis
VRS Compensation--Allowable Cost Categories
1. In the Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking (FNPRM), FCC 17-26,
published at 82 FR 17613, April 12, 2017, the Commission stated its
intention not to reopen questions concerning the categories of expenses
that should be considered allowable costs for VRS compensation. Various
parties commenting in this proceeding nonetheless urge that the
Commission re-open the matter of allowing costs associated with
customer premise equipment (CPE), numbering, outreach, and research and
development (R&D). In addition, Sorenson Communications, LLC (Sorenson)
raises new concerns about allowing compensation for imputed
intellectual property. These issues are beyond the scope of the
rulemaking. The Commission has previously considered and disallowed
compensation for each of these categories, except intellectual
property, which is addressed below.
2. No reason to reopen previously settled disallowance issues. No
party provides a compelling reason to reopen the above issues in this
proceeding, especially in the absence of Administrative Procedure Act
(APA) notice. The Commission does not agree that circumstances have
changed dramatically and sees no material difference from prior
proceedings where these issues were addressed.
3. Even if the issues were not already settled and there was APA
notice regarding them, the Commission would not be persuaded by
arguments to expand allowable costs. Equalizing all VRS-related costs
to a voice telephone user's costs is not part of the Commission's
mandate under section 225 of the Act. Congressional intent to equalize
either network access rates or equipment costs for TRS and voice
service users is not evident in the text of this narrowly drawn
provision, its surrounding context, or its legislative history. In
1990, the year of section 225's enactment, all TRS calls took place
between individuals who used TTYs and voice users. But the high costs
of TTY service rates and equipment were matters of public awareness and
were being addressed through state and federal action outside the relay
requirements of section 225 of the Act. Regarding service costs, the
plain text of this section demonstrates that it solely was intended to
prevent relay users from incurring the added costs of routing TRS calls
through remote relay centers that lie outside the geographical
locations of the parties to a relay call, and nothing more. Congress
had knowledge about, and ample opportunity to direct the Commission to
equalize telephone service costs for TTY users at the time of section
225's enactment, yet it specifically chose not to do so. Accordingly,
the discrepancy between the higher service costs for a broadband
connection needed to achieve access to VRS and the costs of
[[Page 39674]]
telephone service incurred by voice users was not a matter intended to
be addressed by section 225 of the Act.
4. Similarly, at the time of section 225's enactment, it was quite
evident that the cost of end user equipment needed to complete TRS
calls would be significantly greater than the equipment costs incurred
by voice telephone users. The average cost for a TTY was $600-$1000, a
prohibitive amount for many individuals with low incomes. Again,
however, there is simply no indication in section 225 of the Act or its
legislative history of an intent by Congress to require the Commission
to use the TRS Fund or any other mechanism to equalize such equipment
costs. Rather, states developed local programs to distribute TTYs and
other specialized customer premises equipment to low income and other
eligible individuals with disabilities.
5. Further, disallowance of end user equipment costs from
compensable expenses does not discourage the development of improved
technology. Rather, compensation to providers for the provision of free
equipment runs counter to promoting the use of new mobile and other
technologies that are available for use with VRS. The Commission has
undertaken extensive efforts to expand the availability of
interoperable off-the-shelf Internet Protocol (IP) enabled devices for
VRS use, so that individuals who use these services can reduce their
dependence on VRS equipment specifically designed for a particular
provider's network. Providers increasingly run their own software on
off-the-shelf mobile devices, tablets, desktop personal computers, and
laptops, reducing the need for specialized, stand-alone VRS equipment.
Because the Commission's rules require that all providers support a
common standard for relay user equipment (in addition to their own
proprietary standards), the Commission has made it possible for the
software developed according to such standard to work on all provider
networks, thus making it more attractive for third parties to develop
VRS software. These actions demonstrate a concerted effort by the
Commission to further section 225's mandate to encourage the use of new
and innovative technology.
6. By not authorizing recovery of the costs of VRS CPE, the
Commission avoids offering preferential subsidies to certain VRS
providers (i.e., those who rely on the free provision of expensive,
dedicated videophones and other equipment to attract and retain VRS
consumers for their branded services) to the exclusion of others, as
well as avoids encouraging providers to engage in free CPE giveaways as
incentives to use their services. The Commission believes that if VRS
providers are to compete for customers, it is preferable for such
competition to take place with respect to the quality of their
services--which was the intended purpose of section 225 of the Act--not
the equipment they can afford to distribute. The Commission finds no
basis for departing from Commission precedent, and therefore again
declines to allow use of TRS funds to support VRS providers' equipment
costs.
7. Intellectual Property. The Commission concludes that a provider
that develops its own intellectual property is not entitled to have the
imputed value of that property included in allowable costs. First, the
Commission has not previously allowed compensation for the imputed
value of TRS providers' property, whether tangible or intangible, and
the Commission sees no reason to do so under a methodology that is
based on compensating providers for their actual expenses. Any attempt
to value intellectual property would necessarily be speculative and
highly inexact, especially in the absence of evidence based on arm's
length marketplace transactions involving such property. Second, as
noted above, to the extent that a provider engages in R&D to develop
VRS technologies whose purpose is to meet the Commission's mandatory
minimum standards, it is already permitted to recover those expenses
from the TRS Fund. To also compensate a provider for the imputed value
of such technology would be duplicative at best. Third, the Commission
finds unconvincing the suggestion of an analogy between costs incurred
by a TRS provider to license technology from third parties and the
imputation of a licensing fee to be ``paid'' by a TRS provider to
itself. The Commission's cost-of-service methodology appropriately
assesses the cost of VRS based on provider's actual expenses, not
hypothetical expenses that a provider might have incurred had it chosen
to purchase technology from third parties. When a VRS provider chooses
to develop its own VRS technologies rather than license them from
others, it is reasonable to assume that the provider decided that such
self-provisioning would enable it to provide service more effectively
and at lower cost. It is likewise reasonable and appropriate for the
Commission to assess a provider's costs based on its actual
expenditures rather than hypothetical, more costly expenditures that it
might have made but chose not to.
8. In effect, the argument for recovery of the imputed value of a
TRS provider's intellectual property appears to be a way of arguing
that VRS providers should be able to gain additional profit for what
they have invested in R&D. Although the Commission allows providers to
recover their reasonable expenses of providing TRS, in prior decisions
it has disallowed claims for ``profit'' in excess of a reasonable
allowance for the cost of raising capital. Although in the section
following the Commission modifies the method of estimating capital
costs by adopting an ``operating margin'' approach that will allow
providers greater opportunity to recover such costs, the Commission
does not thereby authorize providers to recover additional ``markup''
or profit that goes beyond such reasonable allowance.
Capital Cost Recovery/Operating Margin
9. Replacing return on investment with operating margin. In light
of VRS providers' concerns about the adequacy of the 11.25% allowed
return on plant investment for capital cost recovery in an industry
with very little plant investment, the Commission adopts its proposal
in the FNPRM to replace the current rate-of-return approach to capital
cost recovery with an operating margin approach, allowing recovery of a
specified percentage of allowable expenses.
10. Setting an allowed operating margin. There is wide variation
among average operating margins of different industry sectors, as well
as between operating margins for particular companies and time periods.
Sorenson provides a list of adjusted EBITDA margins for 20 ``leading
publicly traded information technology consulting companies,'' which
Sorenson states is based on data reported by Bloomberg on U.S.-listed
public companies with a market cap of at least $1 billion and with 100%
of their revenue derived from ``IT Services.'' Sorenson notes that the
unweighted average margin for the companies on this list is 15.9%.
11. The Commission concludes that consideration of operating
margins earned in analogous industries may be a reasonable approach to
setting an allowed operating margin for VRS providers. However,
information technology (IT) consulting companies are not sufficiently
analogous to VRS providers for their operating margins to serve as a
reasonable proxy. Unlike IT consulting companies, the bulk of VRS costs
are labor costs, primarily salaries and benefits for interpreters, who
need
[[Page 39675]]
not be highly skilled in technology. The Census Bureau's survey of
public companies' financial data for North American Industry
Classification System (NAICS) Code 541, defined as ``Professional,
Scientific, and Technical Services,'' but excluding legal, shows that
average quarterly pre-tax operating margins for this industry sector
between 2013 and 2016 ranged from 1.8% (in 1Q2016) to 7.9% (in 2Q2013),
averaging 4.6% in the 2013-16 period as a whole and 3.2% in 2016. For
NAICS 5419, a subsector that includes translation and interpretation
services but excludes various less analogous industry segments such as
accounting, architectural and engineering, and computer systems design
services, the average operating margin for the public firms included in
the Census Bureau's survey ranged from 3.9% to 12.2% for the 2013-16
period and averaged 7.4% in the 2013-16 period as a whole and 7.6% in
2016. Government contractors are another category that may reasonably
be viewed as analogous to VRS providers in that they are paid by the
government for providing services mandated by law or otherwise closely
supervised by a government entity. In five surveys of government
contractors by Grant Thornton, conducted between 2009 and 2015, the
majority of respondents consistently reported profit rates before
interest and taxes between 1% and 10%, with the median profit rate in
the neighborhood of 6%.
12. Selecting an operating margin from among this wealth of data
regarding arguably analogous industry sectors is not subject to precise
determination. The Commission notes that for 2016 (or 2015, in the case
of government contractors, as that was the most recent year surveyed),
none of the industry sector surveys described above, other than the one
cited by Sorenson, had average operating margins greater than 7.6%, and
that even the high technology firms cited by Sorenson have a median
operating margin of only 12.35%. Based on the current record, and in
light of the Commission's statutory mandate to ensure that VRS is made
available ``to the extent possible, and in the most efficient manner,''
the Commission concludes that the range of 7.6% to 12.35% represents
the ``zone of reasonableness'' of an allowable operating margin for VRS
providers.
Compensation Rate Structure
13. Over the last four years, the Commission has observed the
results of its 2013 structural reform and rate initiatives, including
the effects on provider incentives, to the extent those can be
discerned. The 2013 plan provided for reducing the rate gap between
highest- and lowest-priced tiers, with the ultimate expectation that
the tiered rate structure eventually would be replaced by a unitary
compensation rate for all minutes, which would be set either directly
or by proxy based on competitive bidding. This expectation was, in
turn, based on the assumption that structural reforms, such as
effective interoperability and portability standards and the
establishment of a neutral routing platform would generate a ``more
competition-friendly environment'' for small providers. There was also
an expectation that, pending the completion of such structural reforms,
the temporary continuation of a tiered rate structure would both
encourage improvements in efficiency and ensure that smaller providers
``have a reasonable opportunity to compete effectively during the
transition and to achieve or maintain the necessary scale to compete
effectively after structural reforms are implemented.'' Structure and
Practices of the Video Relay Service Program; Telecommunications Relay
Services and Speech-to-Speech Services for Individuals With Hearing and
Speech Disabilities, Report and Order, FCC 13-82, published at 78 FR
40581, July 5, 2013 (2013 VRS Reform Order).
14. The record confirms that most of these underlying expectations
and assumptions have not been borne out by experience. First, a number
of the Commission's expectations regarding the pace and content of
structural reforms have proven to be overly optimistic. Improved
interoperability standards were not incorporated into the Commission's
rules until this year, and some aspects of equipment portability, which
was expected to improve the competitiveness of the VRS market by
facilitating consumers' use of inexpensive, off-the-shelf devices, have
yet to secure consensus from the VRS industry. Further, the neutral
video communications platform, which the 2013 VRS Reform Order
envisioned as a key element in enabling small providers to compete
effectively, proved to be impracticable. These developments disprove
the Commission's original assumption that structural reforms would be
far enough advanced to enable the elimination of tiered rates and the
introduction of a market-based methodology upon the expiration of the
2013 compensation plan.
15. Second, provider cost reports overall do not show the major
improvements in smaller providers' efficiency that the Commission
assumed were possible. With the ``glide path'' reductions in VRS
compensation rates, providers have been under pressure to improve
efficiency, and the record indicates that certain providers have taken
significant measures to do so. The weighted average of historical per-
minute costs reported by VRS providers has declined from 2013 to 2016;
however, the decline has been relatively modest, compared to the period
from 2009 to 2012, when average per-minute costs declined by more than
$1.00 per minute. Thus, while it appears that providers have achieved
some efficiency improvements, other factors, such as the lack of full
interoperability, may have limited their success. As a result, the
Commission's expectation that smaller VRS providers would be able to
make substantial improvements in efficiency within the past four-year
period was not fulfilled.
16. Third, updated VRS demand data confirm that the VRS market
structure is largely unchanged since 2013, when ``Sorenson provide[d]
about 80% of the VRS minutes logged every month, and its two principal
competitors each provide[d] another five to ten percent.'' Since then,
the two cited competitors of Sorenson have merged, but it is too early
to predict how that merger will affect the viability of competition in
the VRS market (other than reducing the total number of competitors
from five to four). What is clear, however, is that competitors have
not made significant inroads into Sorenson's market share, and no VRS
provider has been able to grow significantly so as to achieve ``the
necessary scale to compete effectively.''
17. As a consequence of these developments, there remain vast
differences in the per-minute costs of VRS providers, which roughly
track the vastly different market shares of each current provider. As
long as such lopsided cost structures persist, it seems highly unlikely
that any of the non-dominant VRS providers can compete successfully to
gain market share vis-[agrave]-vis the largest, least-cost provider.
18. In the face of these unfulfilled expectations and assumptions,
the Commission must choose from a number of alternative courses to
take. One possible course would be to seek to maximize efficiency by
transitioning to a single rate set at the level of the allowable costs
of the lowest-cost provider, or alternatively, at the level of the
average allowable costs for the VRS industry. This approach would
reduce the cost burden on the TRS Fund, at least in the short term,
but, given the current disparate cost structures in the VRS market,
also would be likely to eliminate all VRS competition. The Commission
has consistently sought to
[[Page 39676]]
encourage and preserve the availability of a competitive choice for VRS
users, because it ensures a range of service offerings analogous to
that afforded voice service users and because it provides a competitive
incentive to improve VRS offerings. Further, the continuing presence of
such competitive offerings is likely to encourage the lowest-cost
provider to maintain higher standards of service quality than if it
faced no competition. Thus, if the Commission was to allow VRS
competition to be extinguished, for the sake of increasing the
efficiency of VRS, the Commission would risk depriving users of
functionally equivalent VRS. Because the Commission believes that, in
the current circumstances, the benefits of such a rate reduction,
through increased efficiency, are not worth the risks to functional
equivalence associated with eliminating competitive choice, the
Commission did not propose this course as an alternative, and no party
advocates it.
19. A second alternative would be to transition to a single rate
set at the cost level of some higher-cost provider--most likely the
next-lowest-cost provider. Due to the current imbalance among VRS
providers' cost structures, however, this method would be likely to
result in greatly increased TRS Fund expenditures, because the most
efficient provider--with the overwhelming bulk of minutes--would be
compensated at a rate far in excess of its actual costs. Such
inefficient use of TRS Fund resources is not permitted by section 225
of the Act if there is a more efficient method of ensuring the
availability of functionally equivalent service. In addition, by
generating an extremely uneven set of operating margins--huge windfall
profits for one provider and minimally sufficient margins or actual
operating losses for the others, taking this approach seems likely to
doom any prospect of the VRS market evolving to a more competitive
structure. Indeed, adopting this approach, as a practical matter, would
inevitably eliminate two of the four existing VRS competitors. A single
rate could not be set high enough to allow a third provider to remain
in the market without raising TRS Fund expenditures and allowing the
windfall profits for lower-cost providers to achieve astronomical
levels.
20. For these reasons, the Commission concludes that the
alternative proposed in the FNPRM--maintaining a tiered rate structure
for the next four years--is the best available alternative at present.
Compared with any practicable single-rate approach, as further
explained below, a tiered rate approach is most likely to ensure that
functionally equivalent VRS remains available and is provided in the
most efficient manner with respect to TRS Fund resources.
21. First, the application of tiered rates rather than a single
rate will help ensure that there continue to be competitive options for
VRS users, an objective that takes on special importance at this time,
in light of the recent attrition in the VRS market. Although there were
six independently owned providers at the time of the 2013 VRS Reform
Order, this number has since been reduced to four. The presence of
multiple competitors, even if less efficient than the lowest-cost
provider, may enhance functional equivalence by ensuring that VRS users
have a choice among diverse service offerings. Further attrition, which
would be inevitable if the Commission sets a single rate at any
realistic level, would further limit the ability of consumers to select
providers based on service quality and features, and would make the
continuing availability of any competitive choice less certain, eroding
the Commission's ability to ensure the availability of functionally
equivalent service. In these circumstances, to the extent that a tiered
rate structure is more effective than a single rate in preventing
further erosion of the competitiveness of the VRS environment, it may
be justifiable on that ground alone, even if overall efficiency would
be somewhat reduced.
22. Moreover, the record indicates that, at this time, a tiered
rate structure is more likely than a single-rate structure to improve
the efficiency with which the TRS Fund supports VRS. Given the major
disparities in service provider size and cost structure, tiered rates
enable the Commission to reduce waste of TRS Fund resources by limiting
compensation that is excessive in relation to a provider's actual
costs. Thus, the Commission is not persuaded that a tiered rate
structure, by allowing payment of a higher effective compensation rate
to less efficient VRS providers, necessarily contravenes the mandate
that VRS be available in the most efficient manner. While the mandate
is for the Commission to ensure the availability of VRS in the most
efficient manner, the Commission must measure such efficiency by
comparing the overall expenditures from the TRS Fund the Commission has
established for that purpose, with the overall results achieved by such
expenditures in terms of TRS availability and functional equivalence. A
single rate structure fails this test of efficiency because it would
cost the TRS Fund more in overall compensation than the tiered rate
structure the Commission adopts.
23. Further, the Commission must consider the value users get for
the compensation paid to providers, and may take into consideration the
extent to which the participation of less efficient providers produces
other benefits in the way of improved services for consumers. In this
regard, on numerous occasions, the Commission has made clear that there
are benefits in supporting less efficient providers that meet the needs
of niche populations, including people who are deaf-blind or speak
Spanish, enabling the entrance of new companies that can introduce
technological innovations into the VRS program, and ensuring that
consumers with hearing and speech disabilities can select among
multiple VRS providers--just as voice telephone users do. While the
Commission is obligated to ensure the efficiency of the VRS program, it
cannot sacrifice functional equivalency in doing so. Moreover, it is
the Commission's statutory obligation not to merely seek a short-term
savings in an accounting sense; rather the Commission must consider the
consequences of its actions in the long run. By supporting the
continued participation of multiple providers, a tiered rate structure
can help to prevent the VRS marketplace from devolving into a monopoly
environment, thereby providing the Commission with much needed
flexibility to consider other approaches that may improve efficiency.
For example, one option the Commission may want to consider in the
future is a reverse auction, in which multiple providers bid for
offering service at the most efficient levels; but such an approach
would not be feasible if all providers except one have been driven out
of the market. A tiered rate structure allows the Commission to set
rates that permit each provider an opportunity to recover its
reasonable costs of providing VRS, without overcompensating those
providers who have lower actual costs because, for example, they have
reached a more efficient scale of operations.
24. The Commission also does not agree that tiered rate structures
necessarily detract from providers' incentives to grow and increase
their efficiency. As to growth incentives, while there could
theoretically be a risk that a provider would ``put the brakes on'' its
growth as it approached a tier boundary, a review of each providers'
compensable minutes over the last few years does not suggest that
providers' growth rates have been affected as their minutes approach a
tier boundary. Moreover, to the extent there is such a
[[Page 39677]]
risk of generating perverse incentives, the Commission believes it can
be effectively addressed by ensuring that tier boundaries are wide
enough to cover a provider's likely growth during the life of the rate
plan. As to efficiency incentives, because rates are being set for a
period of several years, providers will have an incentive to reduce
unnecessary costs so they can increase profits and minimize losses.
25. Further, the tiers set under this structure are not provider-
specific. Rather, each tier is equally applicable to any provider's
minutes that fall within that tier. Accordingly, under the tier
structure the Commission adopts, the provider with both relatively
large and relatively small volumes of minutes are each compensated at
the higher (Tier I) rate for their first 1 million minutes, at a lower
(Tier II) rate for additional minutes between 1,000,000 and 2,500,000,
and at the lowest (Tier III) rate for any minutes over 2,500,000.
26. The Commission also declines to adopt at this time a plan for
transitioning from tiered rates to a single rate structure. The
anticipated developments that the Commission thought would eliminate
any need for tiered rates have not materialized. Not only have
structural reforms been delayed and reduced in scope, but expected
gains in individual provider efficiency have not occurred, the largest
VRS provider's current market share remains approximately the same, and
there continue to be wide disparities among providers' cost structures.
Thus, the Commission's experience to date does not provide sufficient
confidence that transitioning to a single rate structure would be
consistent with preserving the benefits of competition and ensuring the
availability of VRS in the most efficient manner. With additional time,
this situation may change. The full implementation of competition-
promoting interoperability and portability standards, as well as the
introduction of some new reforms in other areas, may offer greater
opportunities for providers to compete more effectively with one
another. Additionally, the Commission is currently gathering comment on
service quality metrics, which, when defined, measured, and published,
will enhance VRS competition by enabling consumers to make more
informed decisions in their selection of their VRS providers. At a
later time, the Commission can revisit the compensation rate structure
issue as appropriate in light of such developments.
Alternative Approaches
27. The Commission concludes that alternative approaches to setting
VRS rates proposed in the FNPRM, including reliance on price caps,
market-price benchmarks, a reverse auction, and direct provision of VRS
by common carriers, should not be adopted at this time.
28. Price caps. It is premature, at best, to commit to a price cap
approach that involves setting an initial, single rate based on, for
example, the costs of a ``reasonably efficient provider.'' Setting a
single rate at any level that permits more than one provider to remain
in the market would provide windfall profits to the lowest-cost
provider, and the wasteful costs that such windfall profits would
impose on the TRS Fund would be extremely high given the disparate cost
structures of the current providers. Such costs will be imposed
regardless of whether the single rate is set under a traditional cost-
of-service methodology or as the ``initializing'' rate to kick off a
price cap plan. Further, the Commission does not perceive any way in
which price caps could significantly ameliorate the competition and
inefficiency disadvantages the Commission has identified above that
lead it to reject a single-rate approach. The multi-year, tiered
transition plan being adopted will provide many of the same benefits as
a price cap, such as predictability in rates and incentives to become
more efficient. In addition, given that the weighted average of
provider's historical costs has declined measurably over the last four
years, the Commission does not believe that the use of such indices is
necessary at this time to ensure that VRS providers can continue to
recover their reasonable allowable costs, including a reasonable
operating margin, over the next four years. Towards the end of the
2017-21 rate plan, there will be another opportunity to examine whether
a price cap approach should be adopted in conjunction with whatever
rate structure approach is selected for the next plan to maintain
efficiency incentives going forward.
29. Reverse auction. Sorenson advocates the use of a reverse
auction to set VRS rates, citing as models the auctions authorized by
the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC) to set rates for
supplying electricity, as well as those conducted by this Commission to
allocate support for Mobility Funds and to select recipients of support
under the Rural Broadband Experiments. However, the auction proposed by
Sorenson differs significantly from these examples. The FERC and
Commission auctions involved bidding for both price and quantity of the
service to be supplied, while Sorenson's VRS proposal would require
providers to bid a price that is not tied to a specific quantity.
Additionally, the Commission auctions sought selection of a single
provider for each service area, rather than multiple providers as in
the VRS market. If a provider has no guarantee of serving a fixed
number of minutes, each provider's bid will likely be based on current
costs associated with the current number of minutes they provide at the
time of bidding. Thus, while Sorenson argues that a reverse auction
would promote competition, encourage greater efficiencies, and provide
stability, it seems equally or more likely to have the opposite
effect--producing a VRS rate that is either well above the average cost
of providing service, or so low as to keep currently higher cost
providers from continuing or new entrants from joining the market. The
reverse auction proposal thus suffers from the same defects as other
single-rate proposals--it forces a choice between setting a single rate
so low as to preclude effective competition and setting it so high as
to provide wasteful, windfall profits to the lowest-cost provider. In
light of the absence of analogous models for successful implementation,
and the other issues discussed above, the Commission declines to pursue
a reverse auction approach at this time. The Commission does not rule
out exploring this type of approach in the future, however, should new
developments warrant revisiting it.
30. Direct provision or procurement of VRS by common carriers. The
Commission also finds little benefit at this time in the alternative of
terminating TRS Fund support for VRS and, instead, requiring common
carriers to provide VRS directly or through contracts with TRS
providers. Sorenson offers no supporting evidence for its claim that
common carriers and other voice service providers could provide VRS
more efficiently on a direct basis than indirectly, through their
contributions to the TRS Fund. Further, no carrier has commented
favorably on this proposal, while a carrier trade association,
USTelecom, affirmatively opposes it. Accordingly, at the present time,
the Commission has no basis to conclude that direct provision of VRS
would advance the mandate to provide VRS in the most efficient manner
or reduce the burden on TRS Fund contributors. Further, the Commission
agrees with the non-dominant providers that competition and consumer
choice
[[Page 39678]]
might not survive a transition to a direct-provision or direct-
procurement approach. It may well be that common carriers would simply
choose to work with the dominant, low-cost provider, rather than
attempt to maintain provider choice for consumers.
31. Market-based pricing generally. While in 2013 the Commission
indicated a strong interest in exploring a market-based approach, it
did not commit to adopting any market-based approach, much less one
that could prove less effective than cost-based alternatives for
meeting the objectives of section 225 of the Act. Moreover, the market-
based schemes proposed in 2013, which assumed there would be a
transition to a single market-based rate, no longer appear to be as
viable today as they did to the Commission at that time. Those
proposals relied on the expected availability of pricing benchmarks
that would in turn result from the establishment of a neutral video
communications service platform. This platform has not been built, and
based on the unsuccessful initial request for proposals for the
platform and the general lack of interest in it shown by most existing
providers, the Commission has decided not to move forward with its
original plan to build this platform. Similarly, support is also
lacking for the other market-oriented idea proposed by the Commission
in 2013: an auction of calls to certain telephone numbers receiving a
high volume of VRS calls.
Tier Structure and Rate Levels
32. Emergent rate. The Commission adopts its proposal to add an
emergent rate to the tiered rate structure, applicable solely to
providers that have no more than 500,000 total monthly minutes as of
July 1, 2017. The Commission concludes that a separate rate structure
for such providers is appropriate for a limited period to take into
account the generally much higher cost of service for very small
providers, encourage new entry into the program, and give such
providers and new entrants appropriate incentives to grow. Rather than
view an emergent rate as a subsidy for providers that have been unable
to attract users, the Commission believes that this approach recognizes
the still unbalanced structure of the VRS industry, as well as the
incompleteness of VRS reforms intended to enhance competition. In light
of the apparently fragile current state of VRS competition and the per-
minute cost differentials, the Commission concludes it would be unwise
at this time to subject two of the current four competitors to the
dramatic rate reductions that would be necessary to fit them under the
same tiered rate structure as the other two, much larger providers.
Further, smaller providers may offer service features that are designed
for niche VRS market segments or that may not be available through
other providers and that are helpful in meeting the specific needs of
particular VRS consumers. By providing an emergent rate, the Commission
can increase the likelihood that, in the near term, even if no new
entrants arrive, consumers can continue to select a service provider
from four competitors instead of two.
33. In order to maintain incentives for growth and avoid subjecting
emergent providers to a sudden drop in the rate applicable to all their
minutes when they reach the 500,000-minute ceiling, providers who are
initially subject to the emergent rate and who then generate monthly
minutes exceeding 500,000 shall continue to be compensated at the
otherwise applicable emergent rate (rather than the Tier I rate) for
their first 500,000 monthly minutes, until the end of the four-year
rate plan, i.e., until June 30, 2021. Such providers shall be
compensated at the otherwise applicable Tier I rate for monthly minutes
between 500,000 and 1 million.
34. For emergent providers, the Commission adopts a $5.29 per
minute rate for each year of the four-year plan. To the extent that
these providers have demonstrated the ability to show consistent,
substantial growth over the past years, provider cost projections
indicate that this rate will afford such providers a reasonable
opportunity to meet their expenses and earn some profit. The Commission
expects that this opportunity should be enhanced with the
implementation of provider interoperability and other competition-
promoting measures, such as the development and publication of service
quality metrics.
35. However, the Commission does not intend that this rate
structure continue to apply to any currently operating providers after
the end of the four-year rate plan adopted in document FCC 17-86.
During the next four years, the provision of a special rate for
emergent providers may not impose major costs on Fund contributors, but
the likely benefits to consumers will also remain very limited unless
these emergent companies manage to use this four-year window of
opportunity to expand their market share. Therefore, after four years,
the Commission intends that all existing providers, regardless of size,
will be subject to the same rate structure (whether tiered or unitary)
under the compensation scheme that then takes effect.
36. Tiers I-III. The Commission also adopts the proposed tier
structure, in which a provider's monthly minutes up to 1,000,000 will
be included in Tier I, monthly minutes between 1,000,001 and 2,500,000
in Tier II, and all monthly minutes above 2,500,000 in Tier III, with
the highest rate applicable to Tier I minutes and the lowest rate
applicable to Tier III minutes. Based on real-world evidence, which
consistently shows the existence of substantial disparities among the
per-minute costs incurred by VRS providers, which are broadly in-line
with the similarly wide disparities in their volumes of minutes, the
Commission concludes that there are likely to be substantial economies
of scale in administrative costs, marketing, and other areas.
37. Further, the existence of persistent cost differences between
the largest and lowest-cost VRS provider and its smaller competitors is
undisputed. To maintain a competitive environment for the near term,
the Commission's most realistic option is to set compensation rates
that allow the few remaining VRS competitors an additional period of
time to offer a competitive alternative to the lowest-cost provider,
while reforms continue to be implemented. In this context, the
Commission's primary concern is not to identify the exact extent of
scale economies but to ensure that tiers reflect the disparate sizes
and cost structures of current competitors. Further, as the Commission
also recognized in 2013, significant potential harm to competition
could result if the rate tier boundaries are too low and prevent
smaller competitors from remaining in the market, while if the
Commission sets the boundaries too high the only consequence will be
that smaller, less efficient competitors may remain in the market
longer than would otherwise be the case, resulting in somewhat higher
expenditures from the Fund. With the intervening attrition in the
number of VRS competitors, the Commission's preference is even greater
today for striking a balance that emphasizes preserving competition.
38. The Commission expands the Tier I boundary to 1,000,000
minutes, in order to ensure that the ``emergent'' providers, as well as
any new entrants, as they grow large enough to leave the ``emergent''
category, will be subject to a rate that reflects their size and likely
cost structure and that is appropriately higher than the marginal rate
applicable to larger and more efficient providers. Tier I, which also
applies to the first 1,000,000 minutes of each larger provider, allows
the Commission to set a rate that is high enough to ensure that each
provider is able to cover its
[[Page 39679]]
relatively fixed, less variable costs. The Commission expands the Tier
II boundary, as well, to 2,500,000 minutes, for similar reasons.
Expanding the Tier II boundaries, which applies to the minutes of all
providers in excess of the 1,000,000-minutes threshold and up to the
2,500,000-minutes ceiling, enables the Commission to set a rate that is
appropriately lower than the Tier I rate, but higher than the rate for
Tier III, which will currently apply only to the largest provider,
whose per-minute costs are far lower than any other provider's. The
Tier II rate can thus be set low enough to ensure that providers with
more than 1,000,000 minutes are not compensated far in excess of their
allowable costs, but high enough to ensure that such providers have an
incentive to continue providing additional minutes of service. By
increasing the upper boundary of this tier, as well as Tier I, the
Commission also limits any risk of eroding a provider's incentive to
continue growing as its monthly minutes approach a tier boundary. The
lower Tier III rate, in turn, will appropriately be the marginal rate
for the largest, lowest-cost provider.
39. Application of rate tiers to commonly owned providers.
Regarding the recent merger of two VRS providers, Purple
Communications, Inc. (Purple), and CSDVRS, LLC d/b/a ZVRS (ZVRS), there
is disagreement among the commenters as to whether the compensation
rate tiers should apply to these now-affiliated companies separately or
on a consolidated basis, prior to their full consolidation. The VRS
compensation system should be designed, as far as possible, to avoid
creating undesirable incentives to exploit the tier structure by
creating multiple subsidiaries for the provision of VRS. However, the
consent decree that authorized the merger between ZVRS and Purple
specifically includes language providing that the two entities will
continue to operate and submit requests for compensation payments as
separate VRS providers, and will be treated as separate entities for
compliance purposes, for up to 36 months after the effective date
(i.e., until February 15, 2020), after which they will consolidate the
operations of the two VRS providers. As applied here, that
determination means that the two companies will be treated as separate
entities for purposes of the tiered rate structure until February 14,
2020, or until such time that these companies consolidate their
operations. After February 14, 2020, or from the date of consolidation
if it takes place earlier, these companies will be treated as a single
provider for purposes of the tiered rate compensation structure. To
ensure compliance with this outcome, the Commission directs ZVRS to
provide the Commission with 60 days notice prior to such consolidation.
40. Rate period and adjustments. As with the prior rate plan, the
new rate plan will be four years in duration. A four-year period is
long enough to offer a substantial degree of rate stability, thereby
(1) giving providers certainty regarding the future applicable rate;
(2) providing a significant incentive for providers to become more
efficient without incurring a penalty; and (3) mitigating any risk of
creating the ``rolling average'' problem previously identified by the
Commission regarding TRS, in which the use of rates based on averaged
provider costs, if recalculated every year, could leave some providers
without adequate compensation, even if they are reasonably efficient.
On the other hand, a four-year period is short enough to allow an
opportunity for the Commission to reset the rates in response to
substantial cost changes or other significant developments that may
occur over time. Given the lack of support for continuing six-month
adjustments, the Commission adopts the administratively simpler
approach of having rate adjustments occur annually over the next four-
year rate period.
41. Rate Levels. In setting rate levels, the Commission seeks to
limit the likelihood that any provider's total compensation will be
insufficient to provide a reasonable margin over its allowable
expenses, and to limit the extent of any overcompensation of a provider
in relation to its allowable expenses and reasonable operating margin.
Further, the Commission seeks to avoid any risk of setting a rate for
any tier that is either below the marginal cost of a provider subject
to that tier or excessively above such marginal cost.
42. Tier I Rate Level. For this tier, the FNPRM sought comment on a
range of possible rates--from $4.06 to $4.82 for the first year and
from $3.74 to $4.82 for the fourth year. The current rate level of
$4.06 per minute (in conjunction with the $3.49 rate currently
applicable to a provider's minutes in excess of 1 million)--is too low
to permit all providers to meet their allowable expenses and earn a
reasonable operating margin. Instead, the Commission adopts the rate of
$4.82 per minute recommended by the non-dominant providers, which will
apply to all four years of the rate period. A Tier I rate at this level
will allow all providers subject to it to recover their allowable
expenses and earn an operating margin within the zone of
reasonableness. This Tier I rate level also provides an appropriate
incentive for emergent providers to grow their businesses beyond
500,000 minutes.
43. Tier II. The Commission adopts a Tier II rate of $3.97 per
minute for all four years of the rate period. For this tier, the FNPRM
sought comment on a range of possible rates--from $3.49 to $4.35 for
the first year and from $3.08 to $4.35 for the fourth year. The $3.97
rate the Commission adopts is roughly in the middle of the range of
Tier II options for the first year. The $4.35 per minute rate advocated
by the non-dominant providers is higher than is necessary to allow
providers to recover their allowable costs and earn a reasonable
operating margin. On the other hand, the current rate level of $3.49,
combined with the current Tier I level, is too low to permit all
providers to earn a reasonable operating margin. Based on the data
reported by providers, applying the $3.97 rate for all four years of
the rate period, in conjunction with other applicable rates, will allow
all providers subject to this rate to recover their allowable expenses
and earn an operating margin within the zone of reasonableness the
Commission has adopted. At $3.97, this rate is also above the allowable
expenses per minute of any provider subject to the Tier II rate, thus
minimizing the risk of deterring such a provider from increasing its
VRS minutes. At the same time, the Tier II rate is at a level that, in
conjunction with other applicable rates, limits any overcompensation of
providers subject to it.
44. Tier III. For this tier, the FNPRM sought comment on a range of
possible rates--from $2.83 to $3.49 for the first year and from $2.63
to $3.49 for the fourth year. The Commission concludes that the rate
level for Tier III should be $3.21 in the first year and $2.63 per
minute in the final year. The $2.63 rate is higher than the average
allowable expenses per minute for the current provider subject to this
tier, and, in conjunction with other applicable rates, will allow
providers that fall into this tier to earn an operating margin over
allowable expenses that is within the zone of reasonableness the
Commission has adopted. However, because this rate is a substantial
reduction from the current Tier III rate, a gradual transition to reach
this rate level is appropriate. Accordingly, the Commission adopts a
rate of $3.21 per minute for Fund Year 2017-18, the first year of the
rate plan period. This continues the ongoing adjustment of the Tier III
rate, under the previous rate plan, under which it dropped by $.38 per
minute per year, as
[[Page 39680]]
the initial rate of $3.21 is $.38 below the approximate average ($3.59)
of the $3.68 and $3.49 Tier III rates applicable during the 2016-17
Fund Year. The Tier III rate will be reduced by another $0.38 in Fund
Year 2018-19, to a rate of $2.83 per minute. For the final two years,
the Tier III rate will be $2.63 per minute.
45. Although Sorenson asserts that a proper analysis of VRS costs
indicates the Tier III rate should be higher, the Commission does not
rely on Sorenson's analysis for several reasons. First, projections for
the second year out (in this case, 2018), which are included in
Sorenson's analysis, historically have had a poor record of accuracy.
Second, Sorenson's cost calculation includes costs that are not
allowable, as well as a 15.9% operating margin, which is outside the
zone of reasonableness the Commission has adopted.
46. Aggregate effect of the rate levels adopted. The approach
adopted here effectively balances the Commission's overarching goal of
maintaining competition and consumer choice with its obligation to
administer the Fund in an efficient manner. When aggregated, if the
tiered compensation rates currently in effect were to be extended for
four more years, assuming the present growth of this service,
compensation payments from the TRS Fund to VRS providers would be
expected to total (over these four years) approximately $1,887,000,000.
This figure would swell to approximately $1,925,000,000, were the
Commission to adopt the single-rate approach proposed by Sorenson at
the lowest rate that Sorenson deems acceptable--$3.73 per minute. This
would not only result in an increase of about $38 million over
extending the current rates, but also would stifle competition in the
VRS market by likely eliminating all but one provider. By contrast,
under the tiered rate plan adopted today, the Commission expects that
the total cost to the TRS Fund will be approximately $1,835,000,000,
which will produce a cost savings of approximately $52 million compared
to current rates and preserve the competitive VRS environment that
consumers now enjoy.
Other Compensation Matters
47. Audits for providers receiving the emergent rate. The existing,
more generally applicable rules regarding audits are sufficient to
address any accuracy issues regarding emergent providers' costs.
Therefore, the Commission declines to adopt a separate, mandatory audit
requirement for providers receiving the emergent rate. However, the
Commission reminds all current and potential VRS providers that their
costs may be subject to audit at any time to assure the accuracy and
integrity of TRS Fund compensation rates and payments.
48. Exogenous costs. In general, the 2007 model for exogenous cost
recovery is procedurally sufficient for addressing provider requests
for compensation for exogenous costs. Substantively, given that the
tiered rates set in document FCC 17-86 are intended to reduce VRS
compensation rates in the direction of cost-based levels that have yet
to be reached, the Commission adopts the following conditions to ensure
that exogenous cost recovery does not result in increasing the
disparity between Fund expenditures and actual provider costs.
Providers may seek compensation for well-documented exogenous costs
that (1) belong to a category of costs that the Commission has deemed
allowable, (2) result from new TRS service requirements or other causes
beyond the provider's control, (3) are new costs that were not factored
into the applicable compensation rates, and (4) if unrecovered, would
cause a provider's current allowable-expenses-plus-operating margin to
exceed its VRS revenues.
49. Effective date. VRS compensation rates historically have been
set prospectively and are normally not adjusted retrospectively unless
an error has been made. In establishing the rates applicable to the
current period, the Commission acted appropriately based on the record,
and the Commission is not aware of any compelling reason to reconsider
those ratemaking decisions. Further, while the Commission found it
necessary in 2016 to retrospectively apply an emergency rate freeze
with respect to the smallest VRS providers, the Commission does not
find that a comparable emergency exists now necessitating further
adjustment of rates for the same period for which they were already
adjusted once on an emergency basis. Accordingly, the Commission
declines to give the new rates retrospective effect back to January 1,
2017; rather, the rates the Commission adopts are effective as of July
1, 2017.
50. The Commission finds good cause to make the rule changes
adopting a new four-year rate plan in document FCC 17-86 effective as
of July 1, 2017. The current rate plan was scheduled to expire on June
30, 2017. Providers have been aware of this pending expiration since
2013, and have further been aware of the Commission's proposal to
establish a new rate plan going forward. To avoid unnecessary
disruption to VRS providers' operations and to ensure the ability of
consumers to continue to place and receive VRS calls, the Consumer and
Governmental Affairs Bureau (Bureau) recently acted to waive the June
30, 2017 expiration of the existing rates and directed Rolka Loube to
continue compensating VRS providers at the prevailing rates, pending
further action by the Commission.
51. As the Commission now takes action to establish a new four-year
rate regime, the Commission directs Rolka Loube to compensate VRS
providers at the applicable rates adopted herein for all compensable
minutes of use incurred beginning July 1, 2017, except that, to ensure
that the release of document FCC 17-86 after July 1 does not adversely
affect any VRS provider, the Commission will not apply the reduction in
Tier III rates to any compensable minutes of use incurred between July
1 and the release date of document FCC 17-86. To implement this
provision (given that minutes of use are compensated on a monthly
basis), the Commission directs Rolka Loube to compensate any provider
with Tier III minutes in July 2017 at a rate of $3.49 per minute for
the first X Tier III minutes, where X equals the number of compensable
minutes of use incurred between July 1 and the release of document FCC
17-86. So if a VRS provider has no Tier III minutes in July 2017, this
provision will not affect it; if a provider has X or fewer Tier III
minutes, then all such minutes will be compensated at the higher $3.49
rate; and if a provider has more than X Tier III minutes, then it will
receive $3.49 per minute for the first X Tier III minutes and $3.21 for
all remaining Tier III minutes. The Commission also directs the Bureau
to provide actual notice to known VRS providers by sending them a copy
of document FCC 17-86.
52. Historical Cost vs. Projected Costs. For purposes of document
FCC 17-86, a review of the past relationships between projected and
actual costs indicates that the most reliable reference points for cost
calculations when rates are set are the actual costs reported for the
previous calendar year and the projected costs for the current calendar
year. The least reliable reference point is the projected costs for the
year after the current year. Accordingly, as a reference point for cost
calculations for purposes of document FCC 17-86, the Commission uses
the weighted average of each provider's actual costs and demand for
2016 and projected costs and demand for 2017.
Other Matters--Server-Based Routing
53. Under the TRS numbering rules, calls that involve multiple VRS
[[Page 39681]]
providers are routed based on the information provided in the TRS
Numbering Directory. Section 64.613(a) of the Commission's rules
currently requires that the Uniform Resource Identifier (URI) for a VRS
user's telephone number contain the IP address of the user's device.
However, the VRS Provider Interoperability Profile technical standard
provides for the routing of inter-provider VRS and point-to-point video
calls to a server of the terminating VRS provider rather than directly
to a specific device. The technical standard thus specifies the use of
call routing information that contains provider domain names, rather
than user-specific IP addresses. To permit the implementation of the
VRS Provider Interoperability Profile, which has been incorporated by
reference into the Commission's rules, it is necessary to amend the TRS
Numbering Directory rule. This change will foster the implementation of
interoperability, thereby enhancing functional equivalence. In
addition, allowing routing based on domain names will promote TRS
regulation that ``encourage[s] . . . the use of existing technology and
do[es] not discourage or impair the development of improved
technology,'' as required by 47 U.S.C. 225(c)(2), and will improve the
efficiency, reliability, and security of VRS and point-to-point video
communications, thus advancing these important Commission objectives as
well. The Commission also finds that server-based routing will not
impair the Commission's ability to prevent waste, fraud, and abuse in
the VRS program.
Other Matters--Research and Development
54. The Commission adopts its proposal in the FNPRM to direct the
TRS Fund administrator, as part of annual ratemaking proceedings, to
include in the proposed TRS Fund administrative budget an appropriate
amount for Commission-directed research and development R&D. These
funds will enable the Commission to ensure that TRS evolves with
improvements in technology. Because the TRS Fund administrator
previously submitted its recommended budget for the 2017-18 Fund Year
without recommending a specific amount for R&D, the Commission also
allocates $6.1 million from the TRS Fund to be used for R&D projects to
be overseen by the Commission in the 2017-18 TRS Fund Year.
Other Matters--Repeal of the Neutral Video Communications Service
Platform
55. The Commission adopts its proposal to delete the rule
provisions relating to the neutral video communications service
platform (Neutral VRS Platform). Although the Commission requested bids
to build the Neutral VRS Platform, no acceptable bids were received,
and the Commission canceled that procurement. Because no party has made
any showing that the Commission should request new bids for the Neutral
VRS Platform or otherwise expressed any interest in utilizing it, the
Commission (i) removes Sec. Sec. 64.601(a)(20) and (45), 64.611(h),
and 64.617 and (ii) modifies Sec. Sec. 64.604(b)(2)(iii), (b)(4)(iv),
and (c)(5)(iii)(N)(1)(iii) and 64.606(a)(4) of the Commission's rules
to eliminate references to the Neutral VRS Platform and VRS
communications assistant (CA) service providers (the entities that
would have made use of the platform).
Other Matters--Technical Correction to the VRS Speed-of-Answer Rule
56. In the 2013 VRS Reform Order, the Commission modified Sec.
64.604(b)(2)(iii) of the Commission's rules, the speed-of-answer rule,
changing it from (a) a requirement to answer 80% of all VRS calls
within 120 seconds, measured on a monthly basis, to (b) a requirement
to answer 85% of all VRS calls (i) within 60 seconds, measured on a
daily basis, by January 1, 2014, and (ii) within 30 seconds, measured
on a daily basis, by July 1, 2014. The United States Court of Appeals
for the District of Columbia Circuit (D.C. Circuit) vacated this aspect
of the 2013 VRS Reform Order. The court ruled that, pending further
action by the Commission, its decision ``will have the effect of
reinstating the requirement that 80% of VRS calls be answered within
120 seconds, measured on a monthly basis.'' The Commission therefore
amends Sec. 64.604(b)(2)(iii) of its rules to comply with the mandate
of the D.C. Circuit and provide for a speed-of-answer requirement to
answer 80% of all VRS calls within 120 seconds, measured on a monthly
basis.
Order
57. In the Order (2017 VRS Improvements Order), FCC 17-26,
published at 82 FR 28566, June 23, 2017, the Commission set aside the
effectiveness of the VRS Provider Interoperability Profile technical
standard until the Commission resolved the apparent conflict between
the VRS Provider Interoperability Profile technical standard, under
which VRS providers employ server-based routing, and the existing
Commission rule, under which they must route calls based on the IP
address of the user's device. Now that the Commission, in document FCC
17-86, has amended 47 CFR 64.613(a)(2) to permit server-based routing,
the Commission reestablishes the effectiveness of the rule amendment
incorporating the VRS Provider Interoperability Profile, adopted in the
Report and Order (2017 VRS Interoperability Order), DA 17-76, published
at 82 FR 19322, April 27, 2017.
Final Regulatory Flexibility Analysis
58. As required by the Regulatory Flexibility Act of 1980 (RFA), as
amended, the Commission incorporated an Initial Regulatory Flexibility
Analysis (IRFA) into the FNPRM. The Commission sought written public
comment on its proposals in the FNPRM, including comment on the IRFA.
No comments were received on the IRFA. This Final Regulatory
Flexibility Analysis (FRFA) conforms to the RFA.
Need for, and Objectives of, the Proposed Rules
59. Document FCC 17-86 addresses server-based routing of VRS calls,
and funding for Commission-directed R&D.
60. First, by amending TRS rules to permit server-based routing,
document FCC 17-86 expands the ways that VRS calls can be routed. Under
a new interoperability standard, calls may be routed to a server of the
terminating VRS provider that serves multiple VRS users and devices,
rather than directly to a specific device. This new routing method uses
the providers' domain names, rather than user-specific IP addresses, as
is currently required.
61. Second, the Commission directs the TRS Fund administrator, as
part of future annual ratemaking proceedings, to include for Commission
approval proposed funding for Commission-directed R&D. Such funding is
necessary to continue to meet the Commission's charge of furthering the
goals of functional equivalence and efficient availability of TRS.
Summary of Significant Issues Raised by Public Comments in Response to
the IRFA
62. No comments were filed in response to the IRFA.
Small Entities Impacted
63. The server-based routing rule amendment adopted in document FCC
17-86 will affect obligations of VRS Providers. These services can be
[[Page 39682]]
included within the broad economic category of All Other
Telecommunications. Five providers currently receive compensation from
the TRS Fund for providing VRS: ASL Services Holdings, LLC; CSDVRS,
LLC; Convo Communications, LLC; Purple Communications, Inc.; and
Sorenson Communications, Inc. The R&D funding will have no impact on
VRS providers.
Description of Projected Reporting, Recordkeeping, and Other Compliance
Requirements
64. Server-based call routing involves the use of domain names, and
VRS providers using this method will need to keep records of such
domain names. The domain names will then be processed as call routing
information, just as other call routing information is processed
currently. The funding for R&D will have no reporting, recordkeeping,
or other compliance requirements.
Steps Taken To Minimize Significant Impact on Small Entities, and
Significant Alternatives Considered
65. Server-based call routing using domain names will be available
to all VRS providers, will not be burdensome, and will advance
interoperability. Greater interoperability will foster competition,
thereby benefitting the smaller providers. To the extent there are
differences in operating costs resulting from economies of scale, those
costs are reflected in the different compensation rate structures
applicable to large and small VRS providers.
66. The funding for R&D does not have any compliance or reporting
requirements impacting small entities. Indeed, small entities are not
covered by the rule.
67. No commenters raised other alternatives that would lessen the
impact of any of these requirements on small entities vis-[agrave]-vis
larger entities.
Federal Rules Which Duplicate, Overlap, or Conflict With, the
Commission's Proposals
68. None.
Ordering Clauses
69. Pursuant to sections 1, 2, and 225 of the Communications Act of
1934, as amended, 47 U.S.C. 151, 152, and 225, document FCC 17-86 is
adopted, and part 64 of Title 47 is amended.
70. Pursuant to section 553(d)(3) of the Administrative Procedure
Act, 5 U.S.C. 553(d)(3), and Sec. Sec. 1.4(b)(1) and 1.427(b) of the
Commission's rules, 47 CFR 1.4(b)(1), 1.427(b), the VRS compensation
rates became effective on July 1, 2017.
71. A copy of document FCC 17-86 shall be sent by overnight mail,
first class mail and certified mail, return receipt requested, to all
known VRS providers.
72. The Commission's Consumer and Governmental Affairs Bureau,
Reference Information Center, shall send a copy of document FCC 17-86,
including the Final Regulatory Flexibility Analysis, to the Chief
Counsel for Advocacy of the Small Business Administration.
List of Subjects in 47 CFR Part 64
Incorporation by reference, Individuals with disabilities,
Telecommunications relay services, Video relay services.
Federal Communications Commission.
Marlene H. Dortch,
Secretary.
Final Rules
For the reasons discussed in the preamble, the Federal
Communications Commission amends 47 CFR part 64 as follows:
PART 64--MISCELLANEOUS RULES RELATING TO COMMON CARRIERS
0
1. The authority citation for part 64 continues to read as follows:
Authority: 47 U.S.C. 154, 225, 254(k), 403(b)(2)(B), (c), 715,
Pub. L. 104-104, 110 Stat. 56. Interpret or apply 47 U.S.C. 201,
218, 222, 225, 226, 227, 228, 254(k), 616, 620, and the Middle Class
Tax Relief and Job Creation Act of 2012, Pub. L. 112-96, unless
otherwise noted.
0
2. Amend Sec. 64.601 by:
0
a. Revising paragraph (a)(12);
0
b. Removing paragraph (a)(20);
0
c. Redesignating paragraphs (a)(14) through (19) as paragraphs (a)(15)
through (20) and adding new paragraph (a)(14);
0
d. Revising paragraph (a)(26);
0
e. Removing paragraphs (a)(45) through (49);
0
f. Redesignating paragraphs (a)(27) through (44) as paragraphs (a)(30)
through (47) and adding new paragraphs (a)(27) through (29); and
0
g. Revising newly redesignated paragraph (a)(30).
The additions and revisions read as follows:
Sec. 64.601 Definitions and provisions of general applicability.
(a) * * *
(12) Default provider change order. A request by an iTRS user to an
iTRS provider to change the user's default provider.
* * * * *
(14) Hearing point-to-point video user. A hearing individual who
has been assigned a ten-digit NANP number that is entered in the TRS
Numbering Directory to access point-to-point service.
* * * * *
(26) Point-to-point video call. A call placed via a point-to-point
video service.
(27) Point-to-point video service. A service that enables a user to
place and receive non-relay video calls without the assistance of a CA.
(28) Qualified interpreter. An interpreter who is able to interpret
effectively, accurately, and impartially, both receptively and
expressively, using any necessary specialized vocabulary.
(29) Real-Time Text (RTT). The term real-time text shall have the
meaning set forth in Sec. 67.1 of this chapter.
(30) Registered Internet-based TRS user. An individual that has
registered with a VRS or IP Relay provider as described in Sec.
64.611.
* * * * *
0
3. Amend Sec. 64.604 by revising paragraphs (b)(2)(iii), (b)(4)(iv),
and (c)(5)(iii)(N)(1)(iii) to read as follows:
Sec. 64.604 Mandatory minimum standards.
* * * * *
(b) * * *
(2) * * *
(iii) Speed of answer requirements for VRS providers. VRS providers
must answer 80% of all VRS calls within 120 seconds, measured on a
monthly basis. VRS providers must meet the speed of answer requirements
for VRS providers as measured from the time a VRS call reaches
facilities operated by the VRS provider to the time when the call is
answered by a CA--i.e., not when the call is put on hold, placed in a
queue, or connected to an IVR system. Abandoned calls shall be included
in the VRS speed of answer calculation.
* * * * *
(4) * * *
(iv) A VRS provider leasing or licensing an automatic call
distribution (ACD) platform must have a written lease or license
agreement. Such lease or license agreement may not include any revenue
sharing agreement or compensation based upon minutes of use. In
addition, if any such lease is between two eligible VRS providers, the
lessee or licensee must locate the ACD platform on its own premises and
must utilize its own employees to manage the ACD platform.
* * * * *
(c) * * *
(5) * * *
(iii) * * *
(N) * * *
(1) * * *
[[Page 39683]]
(iii) An eligible VRS provider may not contract with or otherwise
authorize any third party to provide interpretation services or call
center functions (including call distribution, call routing, call
setup, mapping, call features, billing, and registration) on its
behalf, unless that authorized third party also is an eligible
provider.
* * * * *
Sec. 64.606 [Amended]
0
4. Amend Sec. 64.606 by removing paragraph (a)(4).
Sec. 64.611 [Amended]
0
5. Amend Sec. 64.611 by removing paragraph (h).
0
6. Amend Sec. 64.613 by revising paragraph (a)(2) to read as follows:
Sec. 64.613 Numbering directory for Internet-based TRS users.
(a) * * *
(2) For each record associated with a VRS user's geographically
appropriate NANP telephone number, the URI shall contain a server
domain name or the IP address of the user's device. For each record
associated with an IP Relay user's geographically appropriate NANP
telephone number, the URI shall contain the user's user name and domain
name that can be subsequently resolved to reach the user.
* * * * *
Sec. 64.617 [Removed]
0
7. Remove Sec. 64.617.
0
8. Amend Sec. 64.621 by revising paragraph (b)(1) to read as follows:
Sec. 64.621 Interoperability and portability.
* * * * *
(b) * * *
(1) Beginning no later than December 20, 2017, VRS providers shall
ensure that their provision of VRS and video communications, including
their access technology, meets the requirements of the VRS Provider
Interoperability Profile.
* * * * *
[FR Doc. 2017-17225 Filed 8-21-17; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6712-01-P