Connect America Fund, ETC Annual Reports and Certifications, 14466-14476 [2017-05468]
Download as PDF
pmangrum on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with RULES
14466
Federal Register / Vol. 82, No. 53 / Tuesday, March 21, 2017 / Rules and Regulations
to providing some period of time
between establishing final model
parameters and beginning the model to
allow participants to prepare for the
unique attributes of this model.
Therefore, we seek comment on a longer
delay of the applicability (model start)
date, including to January 1, 2018, and
we will address these comments and
effectuate any additional delay in the
model start date when we finalize this
IFC. If we effectuate any additional
delay in the model start date, we also
would delay the effective date of the
conforming CJR regulation changes so
that the effective date of those changes
remains aligned with the applicability
(model start) date of the EPMs.
To the extent that section 553 of the
Administrative Procedure Act (APA)
applies to this action to further delay
the rule’s effective date for the purpose
of ensuring adequate time for
subsequent notice and comment
rulemaking if that is warranted, this IFC
is exempt from notice and comment
because it constitutes a rule of
procedure under 5 U.S.C. 553(b)(A).
Furthermore, 5 U.S.C. 553(b)(B) permits
a waiver of prior notice and comment if
an agency finds good cause that a
notice-and-comment procedure is
impracticable, unnecessary, or contrary
to the public interest. Similarly, section
1871 of the Act, which normally
requires prior notice and a 60-day
public comment period for rules that
establish or change a substantive legal
standard, permits waiver of prior notice
and comment when there is good cause
for an exception under 5 U.S.C.
553(b)(B). In addition, the requirement
under section 553(d) of the APA for a
30-day delay in the effective date of a
rule can be waived for good cause. The
January 20, 2017 ‘‘Regulatory Freeze
Pending Review’’ executive
memorandum stated that the rules
under review should be delayed 60 days
from the date of the memorandum. In
addition, that memorandum provided
that agencies should consider issuing a
notice of proposed rulemaking and
solicit public comment if they believed
that a delay beyond 60 days from the
date of the memorandum was necessary.
Given that the provisions of the final
rule that provide for a start date for the
EPMs and CR Incentive Payment model
of July 1, 2017 will take effect on March
21, 2017, there is insufficient time to
undertake full notice and comment
rulemaking ahead of the March 21, 2017
effective date. We have determined that
issuing this IFC as a proposed rule, such
that it would not become effective until
after public comments are submitted,
considered and responded to in a final
VerDate Sep<11>2014
13:46 Mar 20, 2017
Jkt 241001
rule, would be contrary to the public
interest, since the models would begin
July 1, 2017 as originally set forth in the
January 3, 2017 final rule, which could
lead to a good deal of confusion for the
public. In setting forth revised effective
and applicability dates, we seek to
ensure that all parties could participate
in any rulemaking resulting from further
review as requested in the January 20,
2017 presidential memorandum.
Therefore, we are publishing this IFC to
delay the effective date of the rule to
May 20, 2017 and to move the
applicability date for the EPM
provisions from July 1, 2017 to October
1, 2017. We are also delaying the
effective date of the CJR regulation
amendments that were to take effect July
1, 2017 to October 1, 2017, to maintain
our policy of aligning these changes
with EPMs and to avoid confusion.
Because we are immediately adjusting
the effective and applicability dates of
the EPMs by 3 months but believe a 6month delay in the applicability (model
start) date to be warranted, in this IFC
we are soliciting public comment on the
appropriateness of a further delay in the
applicability (model start) date and will
take those comments into consideration.
For these same reasons, we find good
cause to waive the 30-day delay in
effective date provided for in 5 U.S.C.
553(d). Based on these findings, this
rule is effective immediately upon
publication in the Federal Register.
As discussed previously, timing
considerations support an immediate
delay to the effective and applicability
dates and necessitate that the delay
operate on a quarterly basis. Moreover,
our ongoing review of the policy,
consistent with the January 20, 2017
presidential memorandum, and our
identification of the possibility of
additional notice and comment
rulemaking to make any warranted
modifications to the policy, further
necessitate immediate delay. As
discussed in the January 3, 2017 final
rule (82 FR 184), under the 5-year
models governed by the rule,
participants will have a significant
opportunity to redesign care. Delaying
the effective and applicability (model
start) dates will prevent participant
confusion and corresponding disruption
to these efforts, ensure that the agency
has adequate time to undertake notice
and comment rulemaking to modify the
policy if modifications are warranted,
and ensure that in the case of policy
modifications, participants have a clear
understanding of the governing rules
and are not required to take needless
compliance steps due to the rule taking
PO 00000
Frm 00048
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
effect for a short duration before any
potential modifications are effectuated.
II. Responses to Public Comments
Because of the large number of public
comments we normally receive on
Federal Register documents, we are not
able to acknowledge or respond to them
individually. We will consider all
comments we receive by the date and
time specified in the DATES section of
this preamble, and, when we proceed
with a subsequent document, we will
respond to the comments in the
preamble to that document.
CMS–5519–IFC
Dated: March 16, 2017.
Seema Verma,
Administrator, Centers for Medicare &
Medicaid Services.
Approved: March 17, 2017.
Thomas E. Price,
Secretary, Department of Health and Human
Services.
[FR Doc. 2017–05692 Filed 3–20–17; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 4120–01–P
FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS
COMMISSION
47 CFR Part 54
[WC Docket Nos. 10–90, 14–58; FCC 17–
12]
Connect America Fund, ETC Annual
Reports and Certifications
Federal Communications
Commission.
ACTION: Final rule.
AGENCY:
In this document, the Federal
Communications Commission
(Commission) takes another step
towards implementing the Connect
America Phase II auction in which
service providers will compete to
receive support of up to $1.98 billion to
offer voice and broadband service in
unserved high-cost areas.
DATES: Effective April 20, 2017.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
Alexander Minard, Wireline
Competition Bureau, (202) 418–7400 or
TTY: (202) 418–0484.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: This is a
summary of the Commission’s Report
and Order and Order on
Reconsideration in WC Docket Nos. 10–
90, 14–58; FCC 17–12, adopted on
February 23, 2017 and released on
March 2, 2017. The full text of this
document is available for public
inspection during regular business
hours in the FCC Reference Center,
Room CY–A257, 445 12th Street SW.,
SUMMARY:
E:\FR\FM\21MRR1.SGM
21MRR1
Federal Register / Vol. 82, No. 53 / Tuesday, March 21, 2017 / Rules and Regulations
Washington, DC 20554, or at the
following Internet address: https://
apps.fcc.gov/edocs_public/attachmatch/
FCC-17-12A1.pdf
I. Introduction
1. With this Report and Order and
Order on Reconsideration (Order), the
Commission takes another step towards
implementing the Connect America
Phase II (Phase II) auction in which
service providers will compete to
receive support of up to $1.98 billion to
offer voice and broadband service in
unserved high-cost areas. The decisions
the Commission makes in this Order
aim to maximize the value the American
people will receive for the universal
service dollars the Commission spends,
balancing higher-quality services with
cost efficiencies.
2. First, the Commission resolves
issues raised in the Phase II Auction
Order FNPRM, 81 FR 44414, July 7,
2016 and 81 FR 40235, June 21, 2016.
The Commission adopts weights to
compare bids among the service
performance and latency tiers adopted
in the Phase II Auction Order, 81 FR
44414, July 7, 2016. Additionally, the
Commission declines to adopt specific
preferences for certain states and Tribal
lands in the Phase II auction and
decline to adopt alternative interim
deployment obligations for a subset of
Phase II auction recipients. However,
the Commission does adopt preferences
that will be implemented in the Remote
Areas Fund auction for states where the
Phase II offer of model-based support
was declined, subject to certain
conditions.
3. Second, the Commission also
considers several petitions for
reconsideration of decisions made in the
Phase II Auction Order. The
Commission denies a petition for
reconsideration of the Commission’s
decision to score bids relative to the
reserve price, grants a petition for
reconsideration of the Commission’s
decision to retain the option to reauction certain areas served by high
latency bidders if a set subscription rate
is not met, and grants a petition for
reconsideration of the Commission’s
decision to require bidders in the
Above-Baseline and Gigabit
performance tiers to offer an unlimited
monthly usage allowance.
II. Report And Order
4. Discussion. The Commission now
adopts weights for the Phase II auction
performance and latency tiers that will
account for the value of higher speeds,
higher usage allowances, and low
latency, but that will also balance these
preferences against the Commission’s
objective of maximizing the
effectiveness of its funds to serve
consumers across unserved areas with
the Commission’s finite budget.
5. The Commission first clarifies that
weights are positive values that will be
added to a particular bid-price-toreserve price ratio to arrive at a score.
Mathematically, S = 100 × B/R + T + L,
where S is the bid’s score, B is the
current bid price, R is the reserve price,
T is the weight assigned to the bid’s
associated tier of service, and L is the
weight assigned to the bid’s associated
latency. Because the Phase II auction
will be a reverse auction, higher service
tiers will accordingly have lower
weights.
6. Specifically, the Commission will
weigh bids so that Minimum
performance tier bids will have a 65
weight; Baseline performance tier bids
will have a 45 weight; Above Baseline
performance tier bids will have a 15
weight; and Gigabit performance tier
bids will have zero weight. Moreover,
high latency bids will have a 25 weight
and low latency bids will have zero
weight added to their respective
performance tier weight.
7. The following charts summarize the
Commission’s adopted approach:
Performance tier
Speed
Usage
allowance
Minimum ..................................................
Baseline ...................................................
≥ 10/1 Mbps ............................................
≥ 25/3 Mbps ............................................
Above Baseline ........................................
Gigabit .....................................................
≥ 100/20 Mbps ........................................
≥ 1 Gbps/500 Mbps .................................
≥ 150 GB .................................................
≥ 150 GB or U.S. median, whichever is
higher.
2 TB .........................................................
2 TB .........................................................
Latency
Requirement
Low Latency ...............................................................................
High Latency ...............................................................................
pmangrum on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with RULES
14467
≤ 100 ms .....................................................................................
≤ 750 ms & MOS of ≥ 4 .............................................................
8. A number of commenters proposed
different ways to apply weights. Some
parties also suggested using positive
weights, while others suggested negative
weights, and some suggested a mix of
both. By adding increasing weight as
speed and usage allowances decrease
and latency increases, the Commission
concludes that its approach is a straightforward representation of the fact that
the Commission values higher speeds
and usage allowances and lower
latency, and should be easier for bidders
to understand and simpler for us to
implement. Moreover, a number of
parties suggested that the Commission
uses percentage weights but suggested
various ways to apply the percentage.
The Commission concludes that their
VerDate Sep<11>2014
13:46 Mar 20, 2017
Jkt 241001
overall approach of adding the weight to
the bid-to-reserve price ratio
appropriately applies the weights
uniformly across all areas, thereby
increasing competition and giving
providers in all eligible areas
opportunities to win. The Commission
also declines to adopt the approach it
suggested in the Phase II Auction
FNPRM, 81 FR 40235, June 21, 2016,
whereby the weight would be subtracted
directly from the dollar amount placed
by the bidder. The Commission is
persuaded by commenters who suggest
such an approach would have a
disproportionate impact on bidders that
place bids for smaller dollar amounts.
9. The Commission’s weighting
scheme for the performance tiers is
PO 00000
Frm 00049
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
Weight
65
45
15
0
Weight
0
25
designed to balance its finite budget
with the reality that, in some areas,
speeds of 10/1 Mbps may be the limit
of what is achievable in the near term
but will still offer significant benefits to
currently unserved areas, including the
potential that service providers may
choose to increase speeds to meet
consumer demand once they have made
the initial investment of deploying to
certain areas. At the same time, the
weights the Commission implements
also attempt to leverage its finite budget
to achieve speeds that are scalable to
meet the evolving needs of consumers
over the 10-year term and the broader
community in areas where it is costeffective to do so.
E:\FR\FM\21MRR1.SGM
21MRR1
pmangrum on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with RULES
14468
Federal Register / Vol. 82, No. 53 / Tuesday, March 21, 2017 / Rules and Regulations
10. The record regarding the weights
that the Commission should adopt for
the different performance tiers varies,
with parties arguing for weights as low
as 5 and as high as 100 between tiers,
and relying on several different
methodologies for establishing the
weights. To sift through these proposals
and establish a reasonable range of
weights to choose from, the Commission
relies on the following propositions.
11. First, the Commission starts with
the principle that the Connect America
Phase II auction must indeed be an
auction, not simply a procurement
process. The Commission wants this to
be a competitive auction where every
bidder has the opportunity to exert
competitive pressure on all other
bidders, and weighting increments of
100 or more would effectively result in
each tier always winning over bids
placed in lower tiers, which may
provide an incentive for bidders in
higher tiers to inflate their bids. The
Commission already decided that all
bids would be considered
simultaneously, and it would not realize
the benefits of competition if one type
of bid effectively always wins over
another regardless of the bids’ support
amounts. Or, as the Commission puts it
in the New York Auction Order, an
‘‘absolute preference’’ for ‘‘one type of
technology or speed’’ would be fiscally
irresponsible ‘‘when more cost-effective,
reasonably comparable options may be
available.’’
12. Second, the Commission takes
that principle one step further and
conclude that every bidder—no matter
the service tier or latency—must have
the opportunity to exert competitive
pricing pressure on every other bidder.
In other words, the total band of weights
must be less than 100. This principle
should maximize the competitive
pressure all bidders bring to bear,
ensuring that even the highest-tier
services take into account the bang-forthe-buck they are delivering to
consumers nationwide. It also ensures
that the Commission examines its
weights holistically, so that the
accumulation of weights does not lead
to untoward and unexpected
consequences.
13. Third, the Commission concludes
that the weights it assign should strive
to reflect the value of higher-speed and
lower-latency services to consumers.
The purpose of the Connect America
Phase II auction is to maximize the
value the Commission can bring for
consumers through the use of scarce
universal service funds—in effect, the
weights recognize that consumers can
and do spend more to receive higher
quality services. Accordingly, the
VerDate Sep<11>2014
13:46 Mar 20, 2017
Jkt 241001
Commission rejects claims to set
weights that normalize the deployment
costs for the performance tiers based on
technology. The Commission sees no
reason to spend scarce universal service
funds to pay for more-expensive
services just because they are more
expensive. Indeed, the value to a
consumer of a fiber-based service is not
its cost but the faster speeds and lower
latencies it offers—and the goal of the
Commission is and must be to minimize
(not maximize) the cost of such services.
Moreover, adding a separate weight to
account for technology costs would be
contrary to the Commission’s objective
to maximize its cost-effective budget
because it could result in paying more
for higher cost technologies when it
might be more cost-effective to support
lower cost technologies. And given the
challenges of determining representative
costs for each type of technology, such
an approach is likely to add complexity
to auction process and could lead to
delay. In a similar vein, the Commission
rejects claims to weight bids in
correlation to the respective download
speeds. Such an approach would have
the effect of heavily weighting the
Gigabit performance tier, without any
evidence that consumers do indeed
value that service in proportion to its
speed or would be willing to spend 100
times more for such service than for
service at the Minimum performance
tier.
14. Fourth, the Commission
concludes that adopting minimal
weights between each tier would be
inappropriate. Consumers clearly value
higher speed and lower latency services,
and minimal weighting could deprive
rural consumers of the higher-speed,
lower latency services that are common
in urban areas. Indeed, such an
approach would likely result in bids in
lower tiers prevailing, leaving all
consumers with minimum service even
though some service providers might be
able to offer increased speeds for
marginally more support. Additionally,
the upcoming Remote Areas Fund
auction will provide an opportunity to
ensure that all Americans at least have
the opportunity to receive some
broadband service. For purposes of the
Phase II auction, the Commission’s aim
is to maximize consumer welfare given
the limited budget they have. The
Commission disagrees with commenters
that suggest that giving bids placed in
the Gigabit tier anything other than a
minimal preference violates its statutory
duty to support reasonably comparable
services because Gigabit services are not
widely available in urban areas. The
Commission is not persuaded that it
PO 00000
Frm 00050
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
must only support services that have
‘‘through the operation of market
choices by customers, been subscribed
to by a substantial majority of
residential customers . . . .’’ First, this
is only one of several factors the
Commission must consider when
establishing the definition of supported
services. Second, the Communications
Act of 1934, as amended (the Act)
makes clear that universal service is an
‘‘evolving level’’ of services, and thus
the Commission must consider the fact
that through the auction it will be
providing support to voice and
broadband services over a 10-year term.
At the same time, the Commission
disagrees with arguments suggesting
that it is a violation of the Commission’s
statutory duty to promote access to
services that are reasonably comparable
to those services offered in urban areas
if the Commission awarded support to
bids committing to provide a minimum
of 10/1 Mbps speeds given the 10-year
support term and the fact that most
urban areas have access to higher
speeds. Instead, the Commission finds
that it is reasonably and responsibly
leveraging the Phase II auction to make
significant steps towards achieving its
overarching statutory responsibility to
support reasonably comparable services
for all consumers. The Commission has
adopted a range of performance tiers
with increasing weights, starting with
speeds and usage allowances the
Commission has deemed reasonably
comparable in the near term and with
maximum speeds and usage allowances
that are scalable to meet the needs of
consumers at the end of the 10-year
term.
15. With those principles in mind, the
Commission reviews the weight of the
record. Most parties proposing within
these parameters suggest increment
values somewhere between 5 and 60.
Parties arguing for smaller weight
increments between speed tiers with a
focus on the lower speed tiers suggest
that the Commission’s focus should be
on maximizing the number of locations
that have access to services that are
reasonably comparable to those offered
in urban areas, and that giving a heavy
preference to higher speed and usage
allowance tiers would be an inefficient
use of the finite budget, favoring high
speeds and usage allowances at the
expense of leaving many without
service. They argue that heavily
weighting bids or assigning any weight
to bids committing to a Gigabit
performance tier would violate the
Commission’s statutory duty to support
reasonably comparable services, and
they claim that consumers are more
E:\FR\FM\21MRR1.SGM
21MRR1
pmangrum on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with RULES
Federal Register / Vol. 82, No. 53 / Tuesday, March 21, 2017 / Rules and Regulations
concerned with having access to service
at reasonable prices than subscribing to
expensive high speed packages. They
suggest that if consumers’ needs evolve
and they begin to demand higher
speeds, carriers will have an incentive
to increase the speeds they offer as
deployment costs go down. Supporters
of narrow weights also claim that such
weights would promote efficiency by
challenging bidders seeking to offer
services in the higher tiers to place more
cost-effective bids.
16. By contrast, other parties argue
that higher speeds and usage allowances
should have heavier weights so these
bids are more likely to prevail. Some of
these parties suggest that the speeds in
the Minimum and Baseline performance
tiers would not be sufficient to
constitute reasonably comparable
services. They argue that the
Commission should focus on supporting
‘‘future proof’’ networks given that
speeds that are reasonably comparable
today may not be reasonably
comparable throughout the 10-year
support term. They also suggest that
certain technologies that may be more
cost-effective today are likely to be more
expensive in the long term because such
networks will need to be upgraded to
meet consumers’ needs, and that it
would be more efficient to support
speeds that can be leveraged by entire
communities. They claim that if higher
tier bids are not given sufficient weight,
bidders able to offer such services will
be less likely to participate, and bidders
in lower tiers could win without having
to place cost-effective bids. Some of
these commenters argue that higher
speeds should be given a near absolute
preference, while others argue for more
moderate increments between the tiers.
17. Taking into account these
principles and the record, the
Commission finds that increments of
15–30 between performance tiers
appropriately balance the concerns of
these potential bidders, and their
representatives, by adopting increments
that are within a reasonable range of the
increments proposed by both sets of
commenters. Based on the
Commission’s predictive judgment, the
Commission concludes that this
approach is likely to promote
competition both within and across
areas by giving all service providers the
opportunity to place competitive bids,
regardless of the technology they intend
to use to meet their obligations. The
Commission weights appropriately
recognize the value to rural consumers
of higher speeds and higher usage
allowances, but bids placed in the
higher tiers will not necessarily win
because of the generally greater costs of
VerDate Sep<11>2014
13:46 Mar 20, 2017
Jkt 241001
deploying a higher capacity network at
higher speeds. Bids placed for lower
speeds and usage allowances will still
have the opportunity to compete for
support, but will have to be particularly
cost-effective to compete with higher
tier bids.
18. The Commission is not convinced
by suggestions that it should adopt
weights that are based on metrics
derived from consumer preference data.
Commenters proposed several
competing data sources and
methodologies in an attempt to
substantiate their proposed weights as
‘‘objective,’’ but the Commission
declines to adopt any of these proposals.
The Commission concludes that
establishing weights based on specific
data is likely to be a drawn out and
complicated process that may further
delay the Phase II auction and may not
produce an improved outcome in the
auction. Moreover, a consumer’s
decision to subscribe to a particular
service may be based on numerous
variables and does not necessarily
suggest that one level of service should
be valued by a particular percentage
over another level of service in areas
where consumers currently have no
options for service. The Commission is
not persuaded that its decision to adopt
weights that are not derived from
specific data is ‘‘arbitrary.’’ Instead, the
Commission adopts weights between
each tier that recognize the value of
increased speeds and usage allowances
and select weights that fall within the
range of weights proposed by parties in
the record that do not seek to give any
one tier an absolute preference.
19. The Commission is not persuaded
that some of the other proposals parties
made in the record regarding how to
approach weighting the different tiers
would be consistent with its objectives
and statutory duties. First, the
Commission disagrees with the
suggestion that it should only weight
bids in higher tiers if sufficient funding
is available to fund all bids at the
Baseline performance tier. While this
approach might permit us to serve more
consumers, the Commission would lose
out on the opportunity to balance its
other objective of funding service that
will achieve reasonable comparability
for the long term. Section 254 of the Act
makes clear that universal service
requires an evolving level of service.
20. Second, the Commission is not
convinced that it should fund extremely
high-cost locations only after the
Commission has funded all bids for
high-cost locations. When it decided to
include the extremely high-cost census
blocks in the Phase II auction, the
Commission explicitly recognized that
PO 00000
Frm 00051
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
14469
in some areas a service provider might
be able to make a business case to serve
extremely high-cost areas efficiently
even though the Connect America Cost
Model has determined an area to be
extremely high-cost. The Commission
has explained that, because extremely
high-cost areas are interspersed among
high-cost areas, including extremely
high-cost census blocks in the Phase II
auction enables parties to build
integrated networks that span both types
of areas as appropriate. The approach
gives bidders the flexibility to decide
how to most efficiently upgrade or
extend their networks. It would
contradict this rationale to refuse to
fund bids in extremely high-cost areas
until high-cost area bids have been
awarded because such an approach
would assume that bids in high-cost
areas would be more cost-effective.
21. The Commission also concludes
that its decision to adopt a weight of 25
for high latency bids appropriately
balances its objective of using its finite
budget in a cost-effective manner, but
also supporting services that will meet
consumers’ needs. The Commission
decided in the Phase II Auction Order
to open the Phase II auction to
participation from satellite providers
‘‘in the interest of making this auction
as competitive as possible.’’ It adopted
objectively measured latency
performance standards to ensure that
consumers received an appropriate level
of service.
22. Commenters propose a wide range
of weights in the record for the latency
tiers, from weights as high as 100 to
weights as low as 10, with commenters
proposing weights lower than 100
suggesting a weight within the range of
10 to 75. Because they propose latency
tier weights relative to their proposed
performance tier weights, the
Commission similarly considers weights
for the latency tiers relative to the
weights it adopted for the performance
tiers above. The Commission is not
persuaded by commenters that argue
that low latency services should be
heavily weighted or by comments
suggesting that low latency services
should always win over high latency
services. Thus, the Commission
concludes a weight of 100 or 75 would
be too high. While many commenters
raise concerns about high latency
services, the Commission already took
such concerns into account when
deciding to adopt objective performance
requirements so that high latency
providers can participate. The
Commission is not persuaded that high
latency providers should have to partner
with terrestrial providers in order to
participate competitively in the Phase II
E:\FR\FM\21MRR1.SGM
21MRR1
pmangrum on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with RULES
14470
Federal Register / Vol. 82, No. 53 / Tuesday, March 21, 2017 / Rules and Regulations
auction. Indeed, by choosing to adopt
alternative latency requirements for
high latency providers, the Commission
has already rejected the concept that
this is the only way high latency
providers can be competitive. While the
Commission welcomes such
partnerships, it concludes that it serves
the public interest to permit service
providers to determine how they are
best able to place a competitive bid,
either by leveraging their own network
or partnering with other providers.
23. Commenters suggesting weights
below 75 argue for a range of weights
between 10 and 45 relative to their own
various performance tier proposals.
Similarly, based on the weights the
Commission has adopted for the
performance tiers above, it concludes
that a weight of 25 would reasonably
maximize competition. A weight of 25
is appropriate because a bidder placing
a low latency bid in the Gigabit
performance tier will not necessarily
win, which will add pressure on such
bidders to make more cost-effective
bids. A Minimum performance high
latency bidder will have cumulative
weight of 90 (65 for the Minimum
performance tier; 25 for the high latency
bid), which will provide a reasonable
opportunity for high latency bidders to
make competitive bids in the lower
performance tiers.
24. Relative to the performance tiers
the Commission has adopted, it also
concludes that a weight of 25 is more
appropriate than a narrower weight like
10 or 15, given the arguments in the
record about the benefits of low latency
services, especially in areas where the
Phase II auction recipient is the only
voice provider. The Commission
concludes that like the weighting
approach it has adopted for the
performance tiers, adopting a moderate
weight will take a significant step
towards ensuring consumers throughout
the country have access to reasonably
comparable services pursuant to the
Commission’s statutory duty, while also
balancing the realities of its finite
budget and the high costs of providing
voice and broadband to these unserved
areas. The Commission rejects
arguments that it should adopt a
narrower weight for latency than it has
adopted for speed tiers to account for
claims that consumers value higher
speeds over lower latency. First, the
performance tier weighting the
Commission has adopted already
accounts for the value of higher speeds
given that, as speeds increase, the
weights will decrease. Second, while
high latency providers suggest that
consumers’ satisfaction with high
latency services has improved so that it
VerDate Sep<11>2014
13:46 Mar 20, 2017
Jkt 241001
is comparable to some cable services,
some consumers have chosen high
latency services over low latency
services, and that terrestrial providers
emphasize speed and price over latency
in their marketing materials, these
claims do not address the concerns
raised by commenters about the
inherent limitations of high latency
services—particularly for interactive,
real-time applications and voice
services given that high latency
providers may be the only voice
providers in the area. The Commission
is not persuaded that it should use
consumer data to establish the bidding
weight between low and high latency
bids. As t explained above, such an
approach has the potential to be highly
subjective, and the process would likely
be complex and time-consuming.
Moreover, the fact that parties subscribe
to more low latency services in urban
areas could be due to a number of
factors and does not necessarily suggest
that a high latency service would not
meet the needs of consumers living in
otherwise unserved high-cost areas.
25. Finally, the Commission is not
persuaded that it should adopt other
types of weights that have been
proposed in the record. Generally, the
Commission finds that the more weights
it adopts to effectuate various perceived
policy preferences, the more the
Commission moves away from the
objective of maximizing the reach of its
budget by awarding bids based on costeffectiveness. Moreover, additional
weights add more complexity to the
auction design and, in turn, this
increased complexity could drive down
interest and participation in the Phase II
auction. In addition, the Commission
explains above why the weights it has
adopted serves the public interest
because they help us balance other
important objectives, like ensuring that
consumers have access to reasonably
comparable services. Parties proposing
that the Commission adopts other types
of weights to advance other objectives
have not demonstrated similarly
compelling public interest benefits.
26. For example, the Commission
declines to adopt weights that would
improve a bid’s ranking if it covers
small areas. The Commission notes that
in some cases, service providers may be
able to take advantage of economies of
scale by bidding on larger areas, and in
those instances bids for larger areas may
be more cost-effective. But the
Commission also declines to adopt
weights that would give a preference to
bids that included 75 percent or more
funded locations within a state. The
Commission notes that there could be
instances when it is more cost-effective
PO 00000
Frm 00052
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
for a number of carriers to offer service
within a state. Similarly, the
Commission declines to adopt weights
to give a preference to small bidders.
The Commission’s focus is on
maximizing the effectiveness of its
funds to serve consumers nationwide.
While the Commission encourages small
bidders to participate in the Phase II
auction and have adopted eligibility
requirements to facilitate their
participation, it is not persuaded that
giving a preference to smaller bidders
will necessarily achieve its objectives
when it is possible that a larger bidder
may be able to make a more costeffective bid in a higher performance or
lower latency tier. Rather than
artificially give a preference to smaller
or larger bids or to small bidders, the
Commission prefers to rely on the costeffectiveness scores of bids to determine
how its budget can best be maximized
to serve the most consumers with
service that is reasonably comparable to
service offered in urban areas.
27. If unqualified bidders are able to
participate in the auction and divert
support from qualified bidders able to
offer service meeting the Commission’s
requirements then consumers would
ultimately be harmed. In the Phase II
Auction Order, the Commission
required bidders to submit with their
short-form applications any information
required to establish their eligibility for
weights adopted by the Commission.
Now that the Commission has adopted
weights for the performance and latency
tiers, it is persuaded that in some
circumstances it may serve the public
interest to require potential bidders to
submit evidence that demonstrates that
they can meet the service requirements
associated with the tiers in which they
intend to bid. The Commission
concludes that such an approach is
likely to provide further assurance that
Phase II auction support will be
awarded to qualified bidders. In a future
Commission-level public notice after
opportunity for further comment, the
Commission intends to: (1) specify what
evidence or other information must be
submitted, (2) establish the conditions
for when such information must be
submitted, (3) adopt the applicable
standards that bidders must
demonstrate, (4) set procedures for
reviewing and validating the submitted
information, and (5) adopt any
additional penalties if capabilities are
misrepresented.
28. While the Commission already
requires that potential bidders make
certain showings in their short-form
applications, the Commission is not
persuaded by claims that this
information will offer sufficient
E:\FR\FM\21MRR1.SGM
21MRR1
pmangrum on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with RULES
Federal Register / Vol. 82, No. 53 / Tuesday, March 21, 2017 / Rules and Regulations
assurance that potential bidders are
qualified to meet the applicable tier
requirements in all circumstances.
Instead, given the varying capabilities of
the technologies that the Commission
expects bidders will propose to use to
meet their obligations, it concludes
there may be circumstances where it
will serve the public interest for the
Commission to make an independent,
objective decision regarding potential
bidders’ capabilities and also require
bidders to demonstrate they have
undergone the necessary due diligence
to ensure they can meet the applicable
requirements before bidding in
particular tiers. The Commission also
disagrees with claims that the technical
showings it requires in the long-form
application will sufficiently address the
Commission’s concerns because it will
not have access to this information until
winning bidders have already been
selected.
29. Finally, the Commission rejects
suggestions that the Commission
intended to adopt the same eligibility
process it adopted for the rural
broadband experiments or that the
Commission would need to reconsider
the eligibility requirements it has
already adopted in the Phase II Auction
Order to require potential bidders to
submit additional evidence in their
short-form applications. Instead, the
Commission made clear that potential
bidders would be required to submit
any information or documentation
required to establish their eligibility for
bidding weights adopted by the
Commission. Moreover, eligibility
considerations are different in the Phase
II auction context than they were for the
rural broadband experiments. The intent
of the rural broadband experiments was
to award support to discrete
experiments. If a bidder was found to be
unqualified after being announced as a
winning bidder, the relevant service
area would be made eligible for Phase
II if the Commission determined that the
area remained unserved. By contrast,
one of the main objectives of the Phase
II auction is to maximize coverage. As
the Commission explained above,
selecting bidders that are later
determined to be unqualified will
thwart this objective because the areas
included in the unqualified winning bid
and other areas covered by bids that
would have otherwise been selected
will lose an opportunity to be served
through the Phase II auction.
30. Although the Commission
declines to adopt state-based
preferences or ceiling in the Connect
America Phase II auction, it is
persuaded that it should reserve funding
in the Remote Areas Fund for any state
VerDate Sep<11>2014
13:46 Mar 20, 2017
Jkt 241001
that did not receive support equal to the
funding declined in the statewide
election process, subject to the
conditions described below. The
Commission continues to recognize the
importance of connecting consumers in
areas that would have been reached had
the Phase II offer been accepted and to
provide sufficient universal service
funds to do so. Accordingly, the
Commission intends to observe the
outcome of the Phase II auction, and
will adopt a process for the Remote
Areas Fund to ensure that states receive
an equitable distribution of funds. In
order to ensure service is extended
expeditiously to areas not supported in
the Phase II auction, the Commission
also reaffirms that the Commission will
seek to commence the Remote Areas
Fund auction no later than one year
after the commencement of the Phase II
auction.
31. Specifically, once the Commission
has had the opportunity to observe the
results of the Phase II auction it will
prioritize bids in the Remote Areas
Fund auction that are placed in such
declined states until it has awarded
enough support to make up the
difference between the total Phase II
declined support and the total support
that was awarded in the state by the
Phase II auction, to the extent possible
based on bids placed, remaining eligible
areas, and budget available. To ensure
that support is targeted to commercially
reasonable bids, the Commission
anticipates that only bids that are at or
below the reserve price would be
eligible for this preference. Any
implementation details will be adopted
when the Commission finalizes the
procedures for the Remote Areas Fund
auction after observing the outcome of
the Phase II auction.
32. The Commission acknowledges
that this approach may mean that some
areas in declined states have to wait
longer to get service than if support was
awarded through the Phase II auction.
Nevertheless, on balance the
Commission concludes this approach
serves the public interest because it
reasonably enables us to achieve its
objectives by first using the Phase II
auction to maximize its budget by
prioritizing cost-effective bids and then
targeting support to areas that remain
unserved in the Remote Areas Fund.
Indeed, the areas where support has
been declined are, according to the
Commission’s cost model, lower cost
than the extremely high-cost areas that
are eligible nationwide. While it is
possible that some areas that would
have received support if the
Commission implemented preferences
in the Phase II auction may be left
PO 00000
Frm 00053
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
14471
unserved after the Phase II auction, it is
also possible that bidders will be
attracted to serve these lower-cost areas
and will be awarded support through
the Phase II auction to the extent that
they place cost-effective bids when
compared to the reserve price and bids
nationwide.
33. For these reasons, the Commission
concludes that this approach is
preferable to adopting weights for the
Phase II auction for states where Phase
II auction support was declined, or
adopting other measures like support
thresholds, ceilings, or rankings in the
Phase II auction. Instead, the possibility
that state preferences in the Phase II
auction could divert funding from more
cost-effective and higher service quality
bids in the Phase II auction, and the
added complexity they would introduce
to the Phase II auction, outweigh the
potential benefits. The Commission
concludes that any inequitable
distribution issues would be better
addressed after the Phase II auction,
after bidders have had the opportunity
to place cost-effective competitive bids
in all states.
34. The Commission disagrees with
commenters that argue that the
Commission should not implement any
preferences for states where Phase II
model-based support was declined.
Instead, the Commission has
acknowledged that an incumbent price
cap carrier’s decision to decline Phase II
model-based support does not diminish
the Commission’s universal service
obligation to connect consumers in
areas that would have been reached had
the offer been accepted and to provide
sufficient universal service funds to do
so. To the extent unserved areas remain
in declined states after cost-effective
bids have been awarded in the Phase II
auction and bidders are willing to serve
those areas with support equal to or less
than the relevant reserve price, the
Commission concludes that it is
reasonable to spend at least as much
support through the Phase II and
Remote Areas Fund auctions that the
Commission was willing to spend
through the Phase II offer of support to
address a similar number of unserved
consumers in these states. And as the
Commission explained above, it is using
this approach as a backstop, once it has
had the opportunity to select bids based
on cost-effectiveness and service quality
through the Phase II auction.
35. The Commission is not persuaded
that it should adopt weights or any
other kind of preferences for states
where the state has either provided state
broadband funding or has committed to
co-invest funds for winning Phase II
auction bids, or where the state is a net
E:\FR\FM\21MRR1.SGM
21MRR1
pmangrum on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with RULES
14472
Federal Register / Vol. 82, No. 53 / Tuesday, March 21, 2017 / Rules and Regulations
payer to the universal service fund.
First, as noted above, these proposals
would add additional complexity to the
Phase II auction, both for the
Commission in designing and executing
an auction that would incorporate these
preferences and for bidders that may
face difficulty in putting together a costeffective bid that accounts for such
preferences. Second, if a state has
implemented a broadband program,
Phase II bidders could use those funds
to supplement the funds they are
seeking from the federal Connect
America program, thereby lowering
their bids so that they are more
competitive. The state’s contribution to
a project will already effectively lower
the amount of support a bidder needs
from the federal universal service fund.
Third, the Commission’s universal
service programs are designed to target
areas where there is not a business case
for service providers to offer reasonably
comparable services at reasonably
comparable rates. By virtue of the
geography of each state, some states
have more of these areas than others and
thus require more support to achieve the
Commission’s universal service
objectives. It would contradict the
Commission’s statutory responsibility to
connect all Americans with reasonably
comparable services if the Commission
were to target federal universal service
support to certain states for the sole
reason that their ratepayers contribute
more into the universal service fund
than the states receive from all
disbursement programs in the aggregate.
36. The Commission is not convinced
that it should set up a separate
mechanism to allocate support directly
to declined states—either in lieu of
those states participating in the Phase II
auction or for those states that do not
receive a certain level of support in the
Phase II auction—or work in
partnership with the states to choose
winning projects based on specified
criteria. Not only would this cause
further delay in getting support to those
areas because the Commission would
need to establish rules for a new
mechanism, it would also contradict its
decision to allocate unclaimed Phase II
support using market-based
mechanisms—the Phase II auction and
the Remote Areas Fund auction. For all
the reasons explained above, the
Commission continues to conclude that
requiring bidders to compete for support
rather than using more subjective
measures to select awardees will lead to
a more efficient use of its finite budget.
37. While the Commission
acknowledges that it conditionally
waived the Phase II auction program
rules to make available up to an amount
VerDate Sep<11>2014
13:46 Mar 20, 2017
Jkt 241001
of support that is equivalent to the
amount of support Verizon declined in
New York to be allocated in partnership
with New York’s New NY Broadband
Program, the Commission did not
guarantee that carriers in New York
would be awarded the full $170.4
million if winning bidders were not
authorized for this amount by the
Commission in coordination with New
York’s program. Moreover, such support
will be allocated to service providers
rather than directly to the state. Such
bidders are required to compete for
funds through New York’s broadband
program and will only be eligible to be
authorized for Phase II support if they
are selected as winning bidders and if
New York commits a matching amount
of support at the minimum. The
Commission also finds that the public
interest considerations in that context
are different than the considerations
here. The Commission’s decision to
allocate up to $170.4 million in
coordination with New York’s program
was premised on the fact that New York
had committed a significant amount of
state support and had already
established a program that is compatible
with the objectives of Connect America
Phase II and that will lead to faster build
out and potentially higher speeds than
if the Commission had waited for the
Phase II auction to allocate the support.
Working in partnership with New York
also meant that the Commission could
eliminate potential overlaps between
the two programs that could otherwise
thwart the Commission’s Connect
America objectives. No other state has
demonstrated that they have adopted a
similar program that would achieve the
same or similar public interest benefits.
38. While the Commission remains
committed to promoting deployment on
Tribal lands, it declines to adopt a
Tribal-specific preference for Tribal
entities or entities choosing to serve
Tribal lands in the Phase II auction. For
the reasons described above, the
Commission concludes that it serves the
public interest to award Phase II support
to the most cost-effective bids, subject to
the performance and latency weights it
adopts above. The Commission’s
decision to score a bid’s costeffectiveness relative to the reserve price
will ensure that service providers that
place cost-effective bids that commit to
serve Tribal lands will be competitive.
Furthermore, the Connect America Cost
Model used to set reserve prices already
takes into consideration many factors
causing varying deployment costs. With
this approach, the auction is able to use
a market-based mechanism to award
support for the purposes of connecting
PO 00000
Frm 00054
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
all consumers, including those on Tribal
lands. The Commission’s action today
does not preclude us from adopting
preferences for Tribal entities or entities
serving Tribal lands in the Remote
Areas Fund auction if Tribal lands
remain unserved after the Phase II
auction and after the Commission has
had the opportunity to observe the
outcome of the Phase II auction.
39. It is unclear at this time what the
effect of a Tribal bidding credit would
be given the Commission’s decision to
adopt weights for service and latency
tiers. The Commission concludes that it
serves the public interest to maximize
its budget by first determining whether
the Commission’s recent policy
decisions will result in cost-effective
competitive bids on Tribal lands in the
Phase II auction. If not, the Commission
will be able to observe bidders’ behavior
in the Phase II auction to determine how
to best implement a targeted preference
that will encourage deployment on
Tribal lands that remain unserved.
40. The Commission is not persuaded
that Tribal governments should instead
select the service providers that will be
serving Tribal lands or that Triballyowned or -controlled carriers should
have the right of first refusal. The
Commission’s paramount goal must be
to maximize the value of the universal
service dollars it is spending on behalf
of consumers—including those on
Tribal lands—and creating artificial
barriers to competing for support or
deploying service on Tribal lands will
only serve to delay the build out of
high-quality services that rural
Americans on Tribal lands want and
need. Such an approach would be
contrary to the Commission’s decision
to conduct a competitive bidding
process in these areas to select service
providers that will efficiently use
support to offer reasonably comparable
services. Moreover, eligible Triballyowned or -controlled carriers will have
the opportunity to participate in the
Phase II auction and potentially win
support if they place competitive bids.
41. The Commission concludes that it
would not serve the public interest to
adopt alternative interim service
milestones for non-terrestrial service
providers or service providers that
already have deployed the infrastructure
they intend to use to fulfill their Phase
II obligations. The Commission expects
that determining whether a recipient
has sufficiently built out its network
and thus would be subject to the
alternative milestones would be a
subjective and possibly time-consuming
fact-specific inquiry. Also, tracking and
verifying different milestones for a
subset of Phase II auction recipients that
E:\FR\FM\21MRR1.SGM
21MRR1
Federal Register / Vol. 82, No. 53 / Tuesday, March 21, 2017 / Rules and Regulations
are based on the timing of consumer
requests would complicate the
Commission and USAC’s oversight
responsibilities. Additionally,
subjecting such providers to more
aggressive interim milestones could
potentially undermine both their
incentives to participate in the Phase II
auction and their willingness to take
steps to deploy facilities prior to being
awarded Phase II auction support.
42. The Commission concludes that
these considerations outweigh the
public interest benefits of the potential
that in some circumstances recipients
will offer the required services faster if
they have to meet more aggressive
milestones. Indeed, carriers that have
deployed infrastructure already have an
incentive to meet their obligations
quickly. First, carriers will want to
supplement universal service support
with customer revenue. Second, Phase II
auction recipients are required to
maintain an open and renewed letter of
credit only until they have certified they
have met their 100 percent service
milestone and that certification has been
verified. As a result, Phase II auction
recipients may choose to accelerate the
rate at which they offer the required
services so that they can close out their
letter of credit sooner.
pmangrum on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with RULES
III. Order on Reconsideration
43. In this Order on Reconsideration
the Commission considers several
petitions for reconsideration of
decisions made in the Phase II Auction
Order. First, the Commission denies a
petition for reconsideration of its
decision to score bids relative to the
reserve price. Second, the Commission
grants a petition for reconsideration of
its decision to retain the option to reauction certain areas served by high
latency bidders if a set subscription rate
is not met. Finally, the Commission
grants a petition for reconsideration of
its decision to require bidders in the
Above-Baseline and Gigabit
performance tiers to offer an unlimited
monthly usage allowance.
44. Discussion. The Commission
declines to reconsider the decision to
score bids relative to the applicable
reserve price. While one of the
Commission’s objectives is to maximize
the number of locations that are served
with its finite budget and ranking bids
based on the dollar per location would
achieve that goal, the Commission has
also made clear that it is focused on
adopting an auction design that
balances this objective with other goals,
including efficiently and effectively
allocating support among the states. The
Commission concludes that ranking
VerDate Sep<11>2014
13:46 Mar 20, 2017
Jkt 241001
bids relative to the reserve price
reasonably balances these objectives.
45. As the Commission explained in
the Phase II Auction Order, it made the
decision to adopt this bid-to-reserve
price ratio methodology to prevent
support from disproportionately flowing
to those states where the cost to serve
per location is, relatively speaking,
lower than other states. It is the
Commission’s statutory duty to support
universal service, which includes
‘‘[c]onsumers in all regions of the
Nation,’’ not just those living in denser
areas. By ranking bids relative to the
reserve price, the Commission will be
providing an opportunity for bidders
across the country to make competitive
bids while also working to maximize its
available funds by awarding support to
the most cost-effective bids nationwide.
Awarding support to those areas where
there are more locations might mean
that the Commission would get ‘‘more
bang for the buck’’ by serving more
locations with its budget, but that
approach might also preclude us from
taking advantage of efficiencies in cases
where service providers are able to serve
areas with fewer locations but with
support that is far below the applicable
reserve price. While the Commission
acknowledges that it could instead
choose to award support to denser areas
in the Phase II auction and address the
remaining areas in the Remote Areas
Fund auction, it concludes that on
balance the public interest will be
served by giving consumers nationwide
the opportunity to be served sooner if
cost-effective bids are placed in those
areas. The Commission notes that its
decision to cap reserve prices for
extremely high-cost areas will help
ensure that its budget is not
disproportionately diverted to these
extremely high-cost areas. Support will
only be awarded to service providers
that can make a business case to serve
these areas with support below the
capped amount and that submit costeffective bids relative to other bids
nationwide.
46. The Commission reconsiders the
Commission’s decision with regard to
re-auctioning areas served by high
latency bidders where there is low
subscribership. Instead, all authorized
Phase II auction recipients will have a
full 10-year term of support if they
comply with the terms and conditions
of Phase II support. While the
Commission had adopted the subscriber
standard to give high latency providers
something objective and quantifiable
that they could track to determine if the
areas they serve would be placed in the
Phase III auction, after further reflection,
the Commission is persuaded that this
PO 00000
Frm 00055
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
14473
approach does not necessarily reflect
the quality of that service or the value
to consumers.
47. First, the Commission agrees that
it may be difficult for high latency
service providers to obtain enough
subscribers to meet the 35 percent
threshold given that by the end of the
third year of support, Phase II auction
recipients will only be required to offer
service to 40 percent of the required
number of locations and may not have
focused on adoption efforts while
working on deploying their networks.
And even if the Commission were to
push this option to later in the support
term, it would be difficult to determine
an appropriate timeframe at this point
without knowing the timing for any
subsequent auctions. Second,
consumers may decide not to subscribe
to a service for any number of reasons,
and the Commission is persuaded by
comments that suggest that many of the
factors that are related to low adoption
are likely to be present in more rural
high-cost areas of the country.
48. While commenters suggest that
they have had success in encouraging
broadband adoption in high-cost areas,
they do not address the Commission’s
timing concerns. Moreover, such a
general statement about their success
does not provide us with adequate
assurance that high latency providers
would have the same experience in the
areas they are awarded support absent
service quality issues. In fact, if the
Commission uses a low adoption rate as
the measure to determine if service is
meeting consumers’ needs, it would
seem to follow that the Commission
should also re-auction areas served by
low latency service providers that have
low subscribership. For these reasons,
the Commission concludes that
subscribership is not an appropriate
measure for determining whether a high
latency service is meeting the needs of
consumers.
49. The Commission is also
sympathetic to claims that even if it
were to come up with an alternative
objective and quantifiable standard, by
simply retaining the option to shorten a
high latency service provider’s support
term it will create uncertainty for such
bidders. The Commission would be
asking high latency providers to commit
significant resources to deploy at a
minimum 40 percent of their network
while reserving the option to take away
their support and potentially fund a
competitor in that same area. Such
conditions may mean that high latency
providers will not participate in the
auction or will inflate their bids to
compensate for the risk, which would
undermine the Commission’s decision
E:\FR\FM\21MRR1.SGM
21MRR1
pmangrum on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with RULES
14474
Federal Register / Vol. 82, No. 53 / Tuesday, March 21, 2017 / Rules and Regulations
to include high latency providers in the
Phase II auction to maximize the budget
by increasing competition.
50. On balance, the Commission is
persuaded that these harms outweigh
the public interest benefits of having the
opportunity to include areas served by
high latency bidders in a subsequent
auction prior to the end of the 10-year
term. As the Commission discussed
above, it acknowledges that some
parties have significant concerns about
whether high latency services will meet
the needs of consumers. Nevertheless,
the Commission concludes that the
performance standards it has adopted
for high latency bidders will offer
sufficient protection to consumers living
in areas served by a high latency bidder.
Moreover, as the Commission explains
above, recognizing these concerns it has
adopted weights that give a preference
to low latency bids to achieve a
reasonable balance between using its
budget cost-effectively to maximize the
deployment of service to unserved
consumers with service quality. The
Commission concludes that the
potential that it would undermine
competition by retaining the option to
re-auction certain service areas could
throw off this balance and potentially
thwart its ability to leverage the Phase
II auction to further the Commission’s
statutory objective of supporting
reasonably comparable services
nationwide within its finite budget.
51. In order to encourage robust
bidding, the Commission grants
Verizon’s request for reconsideration of
the Commission’s prior decision to
require bidders in the Above-Baseline
and Gigabit performance tiers to offer an
unlimited monthly usage allowance.
Instead, the Commission will require
bidders in these tiers to offer a monthly
usage allowance of at least 2 terabytes
(TB) per month.
52. As Verizon explains, a
requirement of unlimited data could
discourage bidding on those tiers,
because a potential bidder would have
to factor in additional investments and
operating expenses to accommodate a
small number of customers whose very
high usage would be responsible for a
disproportionate share of demand.
Rather than require unlimited usage,
Verizon argues that the Commission
could set a very high allowance, which
would provide a greater usage
allowance than the baseline tier but still
permit providers to address true outliers
that increase the cost of providing rural
broadband service. The Commission is
persuaded by Verizon’s argument that
requiring bidders to offer unlimited
usage would raise the cost of providing
higher performance services in rural
VerDate Sep<11>2014
13:46 Mar 20, 2017
Jkt 241001
areas and could discourage bidding in
these tiers.
53. Therefore, instead of requiring
bidders in the Above-Baseline and
Gigabit performance tiers to offer
unlimited data allowances, the
Commission will require bidders in
these tiers to offer a monthly usage
allowance of at least 2 terabytes (TB) per
month. The Commission finds that a 2
TB usage allowance is sufficiently high
to ensure that rural America is not left
behind, and will enable more bidders to
offer higher performance services in
rural areas. Although Verizon originally
suggested that recent urban rate survey
data shows that many urban providers
have usage limits for services of 100
Mbps or more that range from 250 GB
to 1,000 GB (1 TB) per month, it more
recently suggested a usage allowance of
1 TB per month. Verizon cited usage
limits from last years’ urban rate survey
data, and the Commission finds it
reasonable to adopt a higher usage limit
for a 10-year term of support. A data
allowance of 250 GB was the lower end
of the range for comparable services
from this year’s urban rate survey data.
The Commission therefore disagrees
with WISPA’s suggestion that a usage
tier of only 250 GB for the AboveBaseline tier is sufficient for a 10-year
support term. Nor does the Commission
agree with WISPA’s argument there
should not be any usage limits for the
Gigabit tier. WISPA did not raise any
substantive arguments to counter
Verizon’s arguments about the
additional costs of requiring unlimited
usage in high-cost areas. The
Commission is therefore persuaded that
an unlimited usage cap could impose
additional costs on bidders that may
discourage them from offering services
that exceed its Baseline performance
requirements in rural areas. As always,
Phase II winners will be free to offer an
array of service plans, including those
with unlimited usage.
IV. Procedural Matters
54. This document does not contain
new information collection
requirements subject to the PRA. In
addition, therefore, it does not contain
any new or modified information
collection burden for small business
concerns with fewer than 25 employees,
pursuant to the Small Business
Paperwork Relief Act of 2002, Public
Law 107–198, see 44 U.S.C. 3506(c)(4).
55. As required by the Regulatory
Flexibility Act of 1980 (RFA) as
amended, an Initial Regulatory
Flexibility Analyses (IRFA) was
incorporated in the Further Notice of
Proposed Rulemaking adopted in
November 2011 (USF/ICC
PO 00000
Frm 00056
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
Transformation FNPRM, 76 FR 78384,
December 16, 2011), the Further Notice
of Proposed Rulemaking adopted in July
2014 (Rural Broadband Experiments
FNPRM, 79 FR 44352, July 31, 2014),
and the Further Notice of Proposed
Rulemaking adopted in May 2016
(Phase II Auction FNPRM). The
Commission sought written public
comment on the proposals in the USF/
ICC Transformation FNPRM, the State
Action FNPRM, and the Phase II
Auction FNPRM, including comment on
the IRFAs. The Commission did not
receive any relevant comments in
response to these IRFAs. This Final
Regulatory Flexibility Analysis (FRFA)
conforms to the RFA.
56. With this Report and Order and
Order on Reconsideration (Order), the
Commission takes another step towards
implementing the Connect America
Phase II (Phase II) auction in which
service providers will compete to
receive support of up to $1.98 billion to
offer voice and broadband service in
unserved high-cost areas. The decisions
the Commission makes in this Order
aim to maximize the value the American
people will receive for the universal
service dollars it spends, balancing
higher-quality services with cost
efficiencies.
57. First, the Commission resolves
issues raised in the Phase II Auction
Order FNPRM. The Commission adopts
weights to compare bids among the
service performance and latency tiers
adopted in the Phase II Auction Order.
Additionally, the Commission declines
to adopt specific preferences for certain
states and Tribal lands in the Phase II
auction and decline to adopt alternative
interim deployment obligations for a
subset of Phase II auction recipients.
However, the Commission does adopt
preferences that will be implemented in
the Remote Areas Fund auction for
states where the Phase II offer of modelbased support was declined, subject to
conditions.
58. Second, the Commission also
considers several petitions for
reconsideration of decisions made in the
Phase II Auction Order. The
Commission denies a petition for
reconsideration of the Commission’s
decision to score bids relative to the
reserve price and grant a petition for
reconsideration of the Commission’s
decision to retain the option to reauction certain areas served by high
latency bidders if a set subscription rate
is not met.
59. The RFA directs agencies to
provide a description of, and where
feasible, an estimate of the number of
small entities that may be affected by
the proposed rules, if adopted. The RFA
E:\FR\FM\21MRR1.SGM
21MRR1
pmangrum on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with RULES
Federal Register / Vol. 82, No. 53 / Tuesday, March 21, 2017 / Rules and Regulations
generally defines the term ‘‘small
entity’’ as having the same meaning as
the terms ‘‘small business,’’ ‘‘small
organization,’’ and ‘‘small governmental
jurisdiction.’’ In addition, the term
‘‘small business’’ has the same meaning
as the term ‘‘small-business concern’’
under the Small Business Act. A smallbusiness concern’’ is one which: (1) Is
independently owned and operated; (2)
is not dominant in its field of operation;
and (3) satisfies any additional criteria
established by the Small Business
Administration (SBA).
60. Total Small Entities. The
Commission’s proposed action, if
implemented, may, over time, affect
small entities that are not easily
categorized at present. The Commission
therefore describes here, at the outset,
three comprehensive, statutory small
entity size standards. First, nationwide,
there are a total of approximately 28.2
million small businesses, according to
the SBA, which represents 99.7% of all
businesses in the United States. In
addition, a ‘‘small organization’’ is
generally ‘‘any not-for-profit enterprise
which is independently owned and
operated and is not dominant in its
field.’’ Nationwide, as of 2007, there
were approximately 1,621,215 small
organizations. Finally, the term ‘‘small
governmental jurisdiction’’ is defined
generally as ‘‘governments of cities,
towns, townships, villages, school
districts, or special districts, with a
population of less than fifty thousand.’’
Census Bureau data for 2011 indicate
that there were 90,056 local
governmental jurisdictions in the
United States. The Commission
estimates that, of this total, as many as
89,327 entities may qualify as ‘‘small
governmental jurisdictions.’’ Thus, the
Commission estimates that most
governmental jurisdictions are small.
61. The Report and Order and Order
on Reconsideration do not impose any
specific reporting, recordkeeping, or
compliance requirements for entities,
including small entities. Instead, the
Report and Order adopts or declines to
adopt measures that will affect all
bidders participating in the Phase II
auction. For example, the Report and
Order adopts weights for the Phase II
auction technology-neutral service and
latency tiers, and indicates that the
Commission will seek comment on
requiring potential bidders to establish
their eligibility for such weights. The
Report and Order declines to take
further action to give a preference to
certain states, Tribal bidders, or other
types of bids in the Phase II auction.
However, the Report and Order does
adopt a preference for certain states in
the Remote Areas Fund auction where
VerDate Sep<11>2014
13:46 Mar 20, 2017
Jkt 241001
the Phase II offer of model-based
support was declined, subject to
conditions. The Report and Order also
declines to subject entities that have
already deployed a network capable of
meeting their Phase II obligations to
different interim build-out milestones
than the interim build-out milestones
that were adopted in the Phase II
Auction Order.
62. The Order on Reconsideration
declines to reconsider the Commission’s
decision to score bids relative to the
reserve price by instead ranking bids on
a dollar-per-location basis. In the Order
on Reconsideration the Commission
also decides that all Phase II auction
recipients will have a 10-year support
term, thereby reconsidering the
Commission’s decision to retain the
option to shorten the support term of
certain high latency bidders that are
unable to meet a set subscribership
threshold.
63. The RFA requires an agency to
describe any significant alternatives that
it has considered in reaching its
proposed approach, which may include
(among others) the following four
alternatives: (1) The establishment of
differing compliance or reporting
requirements or timetables that take into
account the resources available to small
entities; (2) the clarification,
consolidation, or simplification of
compliance or reporting requirements
under the rule for small entities; (3) the
use of performance, rather than design,
standards; and (4) an exemption from
coverage of the rule, or any part thereof,
for small entities. The Commission has
considered all of these factors
subsequent to receiving substantive
comments from the public and
potentially affected entities. The
Commission has considered the
economic impact on small entities, as
identified in comments filed in response
to the USF/ICC Transformation FNPRM,
the Rural Broadband Experiments
FNPRM and the Phase II Auction
FNRPM and their IRFAs, in reaching its
final conclusions and taking action in
this proceeding.
64. Generally, the decisions that the
Commission makes in this Order will
apply in equal force to all Phase II
auction bidders, including small
bidders. Thus, the decisions made in
this Order generally do not impose
unique burdens or benefits on small
bidders. For example, the Commission’s
decision to adopt weights for the
performance and latency tiers that will
not grant an absolute preference to any
kind of service is unlikely to uniquely
impact small bidders, but it is likely to
help maximize participation by making
it possible for all entities, including
PO 00000
Frm 00057
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
14475
small entities, to be competitive if they
place a cost-effective bid. Additionally,
like all bidders in the Phase II auction,
to the extent smaller bidders choose to
bid in less populated areas, they may
benefit from the Commission’s decision
to retain a bid ranking method that will
score bids relative to the applicable
reserve price rather than a dollar per
location basis.
65. In the Order, the Commission does
decline to adopt proposals for other
weights or preferences in the Phase II
auction, including a preference
specifically for small entities. The
Commission concludes that such an
approach would not further its objective
of maximizing the effectiveness of its
funds to serve consumers nationwide.
Nevertheless, recognizing the important
role that small entities can play in
bringing voice and broadband services
to unserved consumers, the Commission
has already adopted specific eligibility
requirements for the Phase II auction in
an effort to facilitate the participation of
small entities.
66. The Commission also indicates in
the Order that it is persuaded that in
some circumstances it may serve the
public interest to require potential
bidders to submit evidence that
demonstrates that they can meet the
service requirements associated with the
tiers in which they will bid in their
short-form applications. The
Commission will seek comment on this
issue and will consider the unique
challenges faced by small entities in
submitting any required information.
V. Ordering Clauses
67. Accordingly, it is ordered,
pursuant to the authority contained in
sections 4(i), 214, 254, 303(r), 403, and
405 of the Communications Act of 1934,
as amended, 47 U.S.C. 154(i), 214, 254,
303(r), 403, and 405, and sections 1.1,
1.427, and 1.429 of the Commission’s
rules, 47 CFR 1.1, 1.427, and 1.429, that
this Report and Order and Order on
Reconsideration is adopted, effective
thirty (30) days after publication of the
text or summary thereof in the Federal
Register. It is the Commission’s
intention in adopting these rules that if
any of the rules that the Commission
retains, modifies or adopts herein, or the
application thereof to any person or
circumstance, are held to be unlawful,
the remaining portions of the rules not
deemed unlawful, and the application
of such rules to other persons or
circumstances, shall remain in effect to
the fullest extent permitted by law.
68. It is further ordered that, pursuant
to section 1.429 of the Commission’s
rules, 47 CFR 1.429 the Petition for
Reconsideration filed by Verizon on
E:\FR\FM\21MRR1.SGM
21MRR1
14476
Federal Register / Vol. 82, No. 53 / Tuesday, March 21, 2017 / Rules and Regulations
August 8, 2016 is denied in part to the
extent described herein.
69. It is further ordered that, pursuant
to section 1.429 of the Commission’s
rules, 47 CFR 1.429 the Petition for
Reconsideration filed by ViaSat, Inc. on
August 8, 2016 is granted in part to the
extent described herein.
70. It is further ordered that the
Commission shall send a copy of this
Report and Order to Congress and the
Government Accountability Office
pursuant to the Congressional Review
Act, see 5 U.S.C. 801(a)(1)(A).
Federal Communications Commission.
Marlene H. Dortch,
Secretary.
[FR Doc. 2017–05468 Filed 3–20–17; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6712–01–P
DEPARTMENT OF TRANSPORTATION
Federal Railroad Administration
49 CFR Part 270
[Docket No. FRA–2011–0060, Notice No. 5]
System Safety Program
Federal Railroad
Administration (FRA), Department of
Transportation.
ACTION: Final rule; stay of regulations.
AGENCY:
pmangrum on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with RULES
[FR Doc. 2017–05509 Filed 3–20–17; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 4910–06–P
On August 12, 2016, FRA
published a final rule requiring
commuter and intercity passenger
railroads to develop and implement a
system safety program (SSP) to improve
the safety of their operations. On
February 10, 2017, FRA stayed the SSP
final rule’s requirements until March 21,
2017. This document extends that stay
until May 22, 2017.
DATES: Effective March 20, 2017, 49 CFR
part 270 is stayed until May 22, 2017.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
Matthew Navarrete, Trial Attorney, U.S.
Department of Transportation, Federal
Railroad Administration, Office of Chief
Counsel; telephone: 202–493–0138;
email: Matthew.Navarrete@dot.gov.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: On August
12, 2016, FRA published a final rule
requiring commuter and intercity
passenger railroads to develop and
implement an SSP to improve the safety
of their operations. See 81 FR 53850. On
February 10, 2017, FRA stayed the SSP
final rule’s requirements until March 21,
2017 consistent with the new
Administration’s guidance issued
January 20, 2017, intended to provide
the Administration an adequate
opportunity to review new and pending
VerDate Sep<11>2014
13:46 Mar 20, 2017
Jkt 241001
Authority: 49 U.S.C. 20103, 20106–20107,
20118–20119, 20156, 21301, 21304, 21311;
28 U.S.C. 2461, note; and 49 CFR 1.89.
Issued in Washington, DC, on March 15,
2017.
Robert C. Lauby,
Associate Administrator for Railroad Safety
and Chief Safety Officer.
RIN 2130–AC31
SUMMARY:
regulations. 82 FR 10443, Feb. 13, 2017.
To provide time for that review, FRA
needs to extend the stay until May 22,
2017.
FRA’s implementation of this action
without opportunity for public
comment is based on the good cause
exceptions in 5 U.S.C. 553(b)(B) and
553(d)(3), in that seeking public
comment is impracticable, unnecessary
and contrary to the public interest. The
delay in the effective date until May 22,
2017, is necessary to provide the
opportunity for further review and
consideration of this new regulation,
consistent with the new
Administration’s January 20, 2017
guidance. Given the imminence of the
effective date of the ‘‘System Safety
Program’’ final rule, seeking prior public
comment on this temporary delay
would be impractical, as well as
contrary to the public interest in the
orderly promulgation and
implementation of regulations.
DEPARTMENT OF TRANSPORTATION
Federal Motor Carrier Safety
Administration
49 CFR Parts 380, 383, and 384
[FMCSA–2007–27748]
RIN 2126–AB66
Minimum Training Requirements for
Entry-Level Commercial Motor Vehicle
Operators
Federal Motor Carrier Safety
Administration (FMCSA), DOT.
ACTION: Final rule; further delay of
effective date.
AGENCY:
In accordance with the
Presidential directive as expressed in
the memorandum of January 20, 2017,
from the Assistant to the President and
Chief of Staff, entitled ‘‘Regulatory
Freeze Pending Review,’’ this action
temporarily delays, until May 22, 2017,
the effective date of the final rule titled
‘‘Minimum Training Requirements for
Entry-Level Commercial Motor Vehicle
Operators,’’ initially effective on
February 6, 2017.
SUMMARY:
PO 00000
Frm 00058
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
As of March 21, 2017, the
effective date of the final rule published
on December 8, 2016 (81 FR 88732),
delayed until March 21, 2017 at 82 FR
8903 on February 1, 2017, is further
delayed until May 22, 2017.
DATES:
Mr.
Richard Clemente, Driver and Carrier
Operations (MC–PSD) Division,
FMCSA, 1200 New Jersey Ave. SE.,
Washington, DC 20590–0001, by
telephone at 202–366–4325, or by email
at MCPSD@dot.gov.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
FMCSA
bases this action on the Presidential
directive as expressed in the
memorandum of January 20, 2017, from
the Assistant to the President and Chief
of Staff, entitled ‘‘Regulatory Freeze
Pending Review’’ (the January 20, 2017,
memorandum). That memorandum
directed the heads of Executive
Departments and Agencies to
temporarily postpone for 60 days from
the date of the memorandum the
effective dates of certain regulations that
had been published in the Federal
Register, but had not yet taken effect.
Because the original effective date of the
final rule published on December 8,
2016, fell within that 60-day window,
the effective date of the rule was
extended to March 21, 2017, in a final
rule published on February 1, 2017 (82
FR 8903). Consistent with the
memorandum of the Assistant to the
President and Chief of Staff, and as
stated in the February 1, 2017, final rule
delaying the effective date, the Agency
further delays the effective date of this
regulation until May 22, 2017.
The Agency’s implementation of this
action without opportunity for public
comment is based on the good cause
exceptions in 5 U.S.C. 553(b)(B) and
553(d)(3), in that seeking public
comment is impracticable, unnecessary
and contrary to the public interest. The
delay in the effective date until May 22,
2017, is necessary to provide the
opportunity for further review and
consideration of this new regulation,
consistent with the January 20, 2017,
memorandum. Given the imminence of
the effective date of the ‘‘Minimum
Training Requirements for Entry-Level
Commercial Motor Vehicle Operators’’
final rule, seeking prior public comment
on this temporary delay would be
impractical, as well as contrary to the
public interest in the orderly
promulgation and implementation of
regulations.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION:
E:\FR\FM\21MRR1.SGM
21MRR1
Agencies
[Federal Register Volume 82, Number 53 (Tuesday, March 21, 2017)]
[Rules and Regulations]
[Pages 14466-14476]
From the Federal Register Online via the Government Publishing Office [www.gpo.gov]
[FR Doc No: 2017-05468]
=======================================================================
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION
47 CFR Part 54
[WC Docket Nos. 10-90, 14-58; FCC 17-12]
Connect America Fund, ETC Annual Reports and Certifications
AGENCY: Federal Communications Commission.
ACTION: Final rule.
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
SUMMARY: In this document, the Federal Communications Commission
(Commission) takes another step towards implementing the Connect
America Phase II auction in which service providers will compete to
receive support of up to $1.98 billion to offer voice and broadband
service in unserved high-cost areas.
DATES: Effective April 20, 2017.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: Alexander Minard, Wireline Competition
Bureau, (202) 418-7400 or TTY: (202) 418-0484.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: This is a summary of the Commission's Report
and Order and Order on Reconsideration in WC Docket Nos. 10-90, 14-58;
FCC 17-12, adopted on February 23, 2017 and released on March 2, 2017.
The full text of this document is available for public inspection
during regular business hours in the FCC Reference Center, Room CY-
A257, 445 12th Street SW.,
[[Page 14467]]
Washington, DC 20554, or at the following Internet address: https://apps.fcc.gov/edocs_public/attachmatch/FCC-17-12A1.pdf
I. Introduction
1. With this Report and Order and Order on Reconsideration (Order),
the Commission takes another step towards implementing the Connect
America Phase II (Phase II) auction in which service providers will
compete to receive support of up to $1.98 billion to offer voice and
broadband service in unserved high-cost areas. The decisions the
Commission makes in this Order aim to maximize the value the American
people will receive for the universal service dollars the Commission
spends, balancing higher-quality services with cost efficiencies.
2. First, the Commission resolves issues raised in the Phase II
Auction Order FNPRM, 81 FR 44414, July 7, 2016 and 81 FR 40235, June
21, 2016. The Commission adopts weights to compare bids among the
service performance and latency tiers adopted in the Phase II Auction
Order, 81 FR 44414, July 7, 2016. Additionally, the Commission declines
to adopt specific preferences for certain states and Tribal lands in
the Phase II auction and decline to adopt alternative interim
deployment obligations for a subset of Phase II auction recipients.
However, the Commission does adopt preferences that will be implemented
in the Remote Areas Fund auction for states where the Phase II offer of
model-based support was declined, subject to certain conditions.
3. Second, the Commission also considers several petitions for
reconsideration of decisions made in the Phase II Auction Order. The
Commission denies a petition for reconsideration of the Commission's
decision to score bids relative to the reserve price, grants a petition
for reconsideration of the Commission's decision to retain the option
to re-auction certain areas served by high latency bidders if a set
subscription rate is not met, and grants a petition for reconsideration
of the Commission's decision to require bidders in the Above-Baseline
and Gigabit performance tiers to offer an unlimited monthly usage
allowance.
II. Report And Order
4. Discussion. The Commission now adopts weights for the Phase II
auction performance and latency tiers that will account for the value
of higher speeds, higher usage allowances, and low latency, but that
will also balance these preferences against the Commission's objective
of maximizing the effectiveness of its funds to serve consumers across
unserved areas with the Commission's finite budget.
5. The Commission first clarifies that weights are positive values
that will be added to a particular bid-price-to-reserve price ratio to
arrive at a score. Mathematically, S = 100 x B/R + T + L, where S is
the bid's score, B is the current bid price, R is the reserve price, T
is the weight assigned to the bid's associated tier of service, and L
is the weight assigned to the bid's associated latency. Because the
Phase II auction will be a reverse auction, higher service tiers will
accordingly have lower weights.
6. Specifically, the Commission will weigh bids so that Minimum
performance tier bids will have a 65 weight; Baseline performance tier
bids will have a 45 weight; Above Baseline performance tier bids will
have a 15 weight; and Gigabit performance tier bids will have zero
weight. Moreover, high latency bids will have a 25 weight and low
latency bids will have zero weight added to their respective
performance tier weight.
7. The following charts summarize the Commission's adopted
approach:
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Performance tier Speed Usage allowance Weight
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Minimum................................. >= 10/1 Mbps.............. >= 150 GB................. 65
Baseline................................ >= 25/3 Mbps.............. >= 150 GB or U.S. median, 45
whichever is higher.
Above Baseline.......................... >= 100/20 Mbps............ 2 TB...................... 15
Gigabit................................. >= 1 Gbps/500 Mbps........ 2 TB...................... 0
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
------------------------------------------------------------------------
Latency Requirement Weight
------------------------------------------------------------------------
Low Latency....................... <= 100 ms........... 0
High Latency...................... <= 750 ms & MOS of 25
>= 4.
------------------------------------------------------------------------
8. A number of commenters proposed different ways to apply weights.
Some parties also suggested using positive weights, while others
suggested negative weights, and some suggested a mix of both. By adding
increasing weight as speed and usage allowances decrease and latency
increases, the Commission concludes that its approach is a straight-
forward representation of the fact that the Commission values higher
speeds and usage allowances and lower latency, and should be easier for
bidders to understand and simpler for us to implement. Moreover, a
number of parties suggested that the Commission uses percentage weights
but suggested various ways to apply the percentage. The Commission
concludes that their overall approach of adding the weight to the bid-
to-reserve price ratio appropriately applies the weights uniformly
across all areas, thereby increasing competition and giving providers
in all eligible areas opportunities to win. The Commission also
declines to adopt the approach it suggested in the Phase II Auction
FNPRM, 81 FR 40235, June 21, 2016, whereby the weight would be
subtracted directly from the dollar amount placed by the bidder. The
Commission is persuaded by commenters who suggest such an approach
would have a disproportionate impact on bidders that place bids for
smaller dollar amounts.
9. The Commission's weighting scheme for the performance tiers is
designed to balance its finite budget with the reality that, in some
areas, speeds of 10/1 Mbps may be the limit of what is achievable in
the near term but will still offer significant benefits to currently
unserved areas, including the potential that service providers may
choose to increase speeds to meet consumer demand once they have made
the initial investment of deploying to certain areas. At the same time,
the weights the Commission implements also attempt to leverage its
finite budget to achieve speeds that are scalable to meet the evolving
needs of consumers over the 10-year term and the broader community in
areas where it is cost-effective to do so.
[[Page 14468]]
10. The record regarding the weights that the Commission should
adopt for the different performance tiers varies, with parties arguing
for weights as low as 5 and as high as 100 between tiers, and relying
on several different methodologies for establishing the weights. To
sift through these proposals and establish a reasonable range of
weights to choose from, the Commission relies on the following
propositions.
11. First, the Commission starts with the principle that the
Connect America Phase II auction must indeed be an auction, not simply
a procurement process. The Commission wants this to be a competitive
auction where every bidder has the opportunity to exert competitive
pressure on all other bidders, and weighting increments of 100 or more
would effectively result in each tier always winning over bids placed
in lower tiers, which may provide an incentive for bidders in higher
tiers to inflate their bids. The Commission already decided that all
bids would be considered simultaneously, and it would not realize the
benefits of competition if one type of bid effectively always wins over
another regardless of the bids' support amounts. Or, as the Commission
puts it in the New York Auction Order, an ``absolute preference'' for
``one type of technology or speed'' would be fiscally irresponsible
``when more cost-effective, reasonably comparable options may be
available.''
12. Second, the Commission takes that principle one step further
and conclude that every bidder--no matter the service tier or latency--
must have the opportunity to exert competitive pricing pressure on
every other bidder. In other words, the total band of weights must be
less than 100. This principle should maximize the competitive pressure
all bidders bring to bear, ensuring that even the highest-tier services
take into account the bang-for-the-buck they are delivering to
consumers nationwide. It also ensures that the Commission examines its
weights holistically, so that the accumulation of weights does not lead
to untoward and unexpected consequences.
13. Third, the Commission concludes that the weights it assign
should strive to reflect the value of higher-speed and lower-latency
services to consumers. The purpose of the Connect America Phase II
auction is to maximize the value the Commission can bring for consumers
through the use of scarce universal service funds--in effect, the
weights recognize that consumers can and do spend more to receive
higher quality services. Accordingly, the Commission rejects claims to
set weights that normalize the deployment costs for the performance
tiers based on technology. The Commission sees no reason to spend
scarce universal service funds to pay for more-expensive services just
because they are more expensive. Indeed, the value to a consumer of a
fiber-based service is not its cost but the faster speeds and lower
latencies it offers--and the goal of the Commission is and must be to
minimize (not maximize) the cost of such services. Moreover, adding a
separate weight to account for technology costs would be contrary to
the Commission's objective to maximize its cost-effective budget
because it could result in paying more for higher cost technologies
when it might be more cost-effective to support lower cost
technologies. And given the challenges of determining representative
costs for each type of technology, such an approach is likely to add
complexity to auction process and could lead to delay. In a similar
vein, the Commission rejects claims to weight bids in correlation to
the respective download speeds. Such an approach would have the effect
of heavily weighting the Gigabit performance tier, without any evidence
that consumers do indeed value that service in proportion to its speed
or would be willing to spend 100 times more for such service than for
service at the Minimum performance tier.
14. Fourth, the Commission concludes that adopting minimal weights
between each tier would be inappropriate. Consumers clearly value
higher speed and lower latency services, and minimal weighting could
deprive rural consumers of the higher-speed, lower latency services
that are common in urban areas. Indeed, such an approach would likely
result in bids in lower tiers prevailing, leaving all consumers with
minimum service even though some service providers might be able to
offer increased speeds for marginally more support. Additionally, the
upcoming Remote Areas Fund auction will provide an opportunity to
ensure that all Americans at least have the opportunity to receive some
broadband service. For purposes of the Phase II auction, the
Commission's aim is to maximize consumer welfare given the limited
budget they have. The Commission disagrees with commenters that suggest
that giving bids placed in the Gigabit tier anything other than a
minimal preference violates its statutory duty to support reasonably
comparable services because Gigabit services are not widely available
in urban areas. The Commission is not persuaded that it must only
support services that have ``through the operation of market choices by
customers, been subscribed to by a substantial majority of residential
customers . . . .'' First, this is only one of several factors the
Commission must consider when establishing the definition of supported
services. Second, the Communications Act of 1934, as amended (the Act)
makes clear that universal service is an ``evolving level'' of
services, and thus the Commission must consider the fact that through
the auction it will be providing support to voice and broadband
services over a 10-year term. At the same time, the Commission
disagrees with arguments suggesting that it is a violation of the
Commission's statutory duty to promote access to services that are
reasonably comparable to those services offered in urban areas if the
Commission awarded support to bids committing to provide a minimum of
10/1 Mbps speeds given the 10-year support term and the fact that most
urban areas have access to higher speeds. Instead, the Commission finds
that it is reasonably and responsibly leveraging the Phase II auction
to make significant steps towards achieving its overarching statutory
responsibility to support reasonably comparable services for all
consumers. The Commission has adopted a range of performance tiers with
increasing weights, starting with speeds and usage allowances the
Commission has deemed reasonably comparable in the near term and with
maximum speeds and usage allowances that are scalable to meet the needs
of consumers at the end of the 10-year term.
15. With those principles in mind, the Commission reviews the
weight of the record. Most parties proposing within these parameters
suggest increment values somewhere between 5 and 60. Parties arguing
for smaller weight increments between speed tiers with a focus on the
lower speed tiers suggest that the Commission's focus should be on
maximizing the number of locations that have access to services that
are reasonably comparable to those offered in urban areas, and that
giving a heavy preference to higher speed and usage allowance tiers
would be an inefficient use of the finite budget, favoring high speeds
and usage allowances at the expense of leaving many without service.
They argue that heavily weighting bids or assigning any weight to bids
committing to a Gigabit performance tier would violate the Commission's
statutory duty to support reasonably comparable services, and they
claim that consumers are more
[[Page 14469]]
concerned with having access to service at reasonable prices than
subscribing to expensive high speed packages. They suggest that if
consumers' needs evolve and they begin to demand higher speeds,
carriers will have an incentive to increase the speeds they offer as
deployment costs go down. Supporters of narrow weights also claim that
such weights would promote efficiency by challenging bidders seeking to
offer services in the higher tiers to place more cost-effective bids.
16. By contrast, other parties argue that higher speeds and usage
allowances should have heavier weights so these bids are more likely to
prevail. Some of these parties suggest that the speeds in the Minimum
and Baseline performance tiers would not be sufficient to constitute
reasonably comparable services. They argue that the Commission should
focus on supporting ``future proof'' networks given that speeds that
are reasonably comparable today may not be reasonably comparable
throughout the 10-year support term. They also suggest that certain
technologies that may be more cost-effective today are likely to be
more expensive in the long term because such networks will need to be
upgraded to meet consumers' needs, and that it would be more efficient
to support speeds that can be leveraged by entire communities. They
claim that if higher tier bids are not given sufficient weight, bidders
able to offer such services will be less likely to participate, and
bidders in lower tiers could win without having to place cost-effective
bids. Some of these commenters argue that higher speeds should be given
a near absolute preference, while others argue for more moderate
increments between the tiers.
17. Taking into account these principles and the record, the
Commission finds that increments of 15-30 between performance tiers
appropriately balance the concerns of these potential bidders, and
their representatives, by adopting increments that are within a
reasonable range of the increments proposed by both sets of commenters.
Based on the Commission's predictive judgment, the Commission concludes
that this approach is likely to promote competition both within and
across areas by giving all service providers the opportunity to place
competitive bids, regardless of the technology they intend to use to
meet their obligations. The Commission weights appropriately recognize
the value to rural consumers of higher speeds and higher usage
allowances, but bids placed in the higher tiers will not necessarily
win because of the generally greater costs of deploying a higher
capacity network at higher speeds. Bids placed for lower speeds and
usage allowances will still have the opportunity to compete for
support, but will have to be particularly cost-effective to compete
with higher tier bids.
18. The Commission is not convinced by suggestions that it should
adopt weights that are based on metrics derived from consumer
preference data. Commenters proposed several competing data sources and
methodologies in an attempt to substantiate their proposed weights as
``objective,'' but the Commission declines to adopt any of these
proposals. The Commission concludes that establishing weights based on
specific data is likely to be a drawn out and complicated process that
may further delay the Phase II auction and may not produce an improved
outcome in the auction. Moreover, a consumer's decision to subscribe to
a particular service may be based on numerous variables and does not
necessarily suggest that one level of service should be valued by a
particular percentage over another level of service in areas where
consumers currently have no options for service. The Commission is not
persuaded that its decision to adopt weights that are not derived from
specific data is ``arbitrary.'' Instead, the Commission adopts weights
between each tier that recognize the value of increased speeds and
usage allowances and select weights that fall within the range of
weights proposed by parties in the record that do not seek to give any
one tier an absolute preference.
19. The Commission is not persuaded that some of the other
proposals parties made in the record regarding how to approach
weighting the different tiers would be consistent with its objectives
and statutory duties. First, the Commission disagrees with the
suggestion that it should only weight bids in higher tiers if
sufficient funding is available to fund all bids at the Baseline
performance tier. While this approach might permit us to serve more
consumers, the Commission would lose out on the opportunity to balance
its other objective of funding service that will achieve reasonable
comparability for the long term. Section 254 of the Act makes clear
that universal service requires an evolving level of service.
20. Second, the Commission is not convinced that it should fund
extremely high-cost locations only after the Commission has funded all
bids for high-cost locations. When it decided to include the extremely
high-cost census blocks in the Phase II auction, the Commission
explicitly recognized that in some areas a service provider might be
able to make a business case to serve extremely high-cost areas
efficiently even though the Connect America Cost Model has determined
an area to be extremely high-cost. The Commission has explained that,
because extremely high-cost areas are interspersed among high-cost
areas, including extremely high-cost census blocks in the Phase II
auction enables parties to build integrated networks that span both
types of areas as appropriate. The approach gives bidders the
flexibility to decide how to most efficiently upgrade or extend their
networks. It would contradict this rationale to refuse to fund bids in
extremely high-cost areas until high-cost area bids have been awarded
because such an approach would assume that bids in high-cost areas
would be more cost-effective.
21. The Commission also concludes that its decision to adopt a
weight of 25 for high latency bids appropriately balances its objective
of using its finite budget in a cost-effective manner, but also
supporting services that will meet consumers' needs. The Commission
decided in the Phase II Auction Order to open the Phase II auction to
participation from satellite providers ``in the interest of making this
auction as competitive as possible.'' It adopted objectively measured
latency performance standards to ensure that consumers received an
appropriate level of service.
22. Commenters propose a wide range of weights in the record for
the latency tiers, from weights as high as 100 to weights as low as 10,
with commenters proposing weights lower than 100 suggesting a weight
within the range of 10 to 75. Because they propose latency tier weights
relative to their proposed performance tier weights, the Commission
similarly considers weights for the latency tiers relative to the
weights it adopted for the performance tiers above. The Commission is
not persuaded by commenters that argue that low latency services should
be heavily weighted or by comments suggesting that low latency services
should always win over high latency services. Thus, the Commission
concludes a weight of 100 or 75 would be too high. While many
commenters raise concerns about high latency services, the Commission
already took such concerns into account when deciding to adopt
objective performance requirements so that high latency providers can
participate. The Commission is not persuaded that high latency
providers should have to partner with terrestrial providers in order to
participate competitively in the Phase II
[[Page 14470]]
auction. Indeed, by choosing to adopt alternative latency requirements
for high latency providers, the Commission has already rejected the
concept that this is the only way high latency providers can be
competitive. While the Commission welcomes such partnerships, it
concludes that it serves the public interest to permit service
providers to determine how they are best able to place a competitive
bid, either by leveraging their own network or partnering with other
providers.
23. Commenters suggesting weights below 75 argue for a range of
weights between 10 and 45 relative to their own various performance
tier proposals. Similarly, based on the weights the Commission has
adopted for the performance tiers above, it concludes that a weight of
25 would reasonably maximize competition. A weight of 25 is appropriate
because a bidder placing a low latency bid in the Gigabit performance
tier will not necessarily win, which will add pressure on such bidders
to make more cost-effective bids. A Minimum performance high latency
bidder will have cumulative weight of 90 (65 for the Minimum
performance tier; 25 for the high latency bid), which will provide a
reasonable opportunity for high latency bidders to make competitive
bids in the lower performance tiers.
24. Relative to the performance tiers the Commission has adopted,
it also concludes that a weight of 25 is more appropriate than a
narrower weight like 10 or 15, given the arguments in the record about
the benefits of low latency services, especially in areas where the
Phase II auction recipient is the only voice provider. The Commission
concludes that like the weighting approach it has adopted for the
performance tiers, adopting a moderate weight will take a significant
step towards ensuring consumers throughout the country have access to
reasonably comparable services pursuant to the Commission's statutory
duty, while also balancing the realities of its finite budget and the
high costs of providing voice and broadband to these unserved areas.
The Commission rejects arguments that it should adopt a narrower weight
for latency than it has adopted for speed tiers to account for claims
that consumers value higher speeds over lower latency. First, the
performance tier weighting the Commission has adopted already accounts
for the value of higher speeds given that, as speeds increase, the
weights will decrease. Second, while high latency providers suggest
that consumers' satisfaction with high latency services has improved so
that it is comparable to some cable services, some consumers have
chosen high latency services over low latency services, and that
terrestrial providers emphasize speed and price over latency in their
marketing materials, these claims do not address the concerns raised by
commenters about the inherent limitations of high latency services--
particularly for interactive, real-time applications and voice services
given that high latency providers may be the only voice providers in
the area. The Commission is not persuaded that it should use consumer
data to establish the bidding weight between low and high latency bids.
As t explained above, such an approach has the potential to be highly
subjective, and the process would likely be complex and time-consuming.
Moreover, the fact that parties subscribe to more low latency services
in urban areas could be due to a number of factors and does not
necessarily suggest that a high latency service would not meet the
needs of consumers living in otherwise unserved high-cost areas.
25. Finally, the Commission is not persuaded that it should adopt
other types of weights that have been proposed in the record.
Generally, the Commission finds that the more weights it adopts to
effectuate various perceived policy preferences, the more the
Commission moves away from the objective of maximizing the reach of its
budget by awarding bids based on cost-effectiveness. Moreover,
additional weights add more complexity to the auction design and, in
turn, this increased complexity could drive down interest and
participation in the Phase II auction. In addition, the Commission
explains above why the weights it has adopted serves the public
interest because they help us balance other important objectives, like
ensuring that consumers have access to reasonably comparable services.
Parties proposing that the Commission adopts other types of weights to
advance other objectives have not demonstrated similarly compelling
public interest benefits.
26. For example, the Commission declines to adopt weights that
would improve a bid's ranking if it covers small areas. The Commission
notes that in some cases, service providers may be able to take
advantage of economies of scale by bidding on larger areas, and in
those instances bids for larger areas may be more cost-effective. But
the Commission also declines to adopt weights that would give a
preference to bids that included 75 percent or more funded locations
within a state. The Commission notes that there could be instances when
it is more cost-effective for a number of carriers to offer service
within a state. Similarly, the Commission declines to adopt weights to
give a preference to small bidders. The Commission's focus is on
maximizing the effectiveness of its funds to serve consumers
nationwide. While the Commission encourages small bidders to
participate in the Phase II auction and have adopted eligibility
requirements to facilitate their participation, it is not persuaded
that giving a preference to smaller bidders will necessarily achieve
its objectives when it is possible that a larger bidder may be able to
make a more cost-effective bid in a higher performance or lower latency
tier. Rather than artificially give a preference to smaller or larger
bids or to small bidders, the Commission prefers to rely on the cost-
effectiveness scores of bids to determine how its budget can best be
maximized to serve the most consumers with service that is reasonably
comparable to service offered in urban areas.
27. If unqualified bidders are able to participate in the auction
and divert support from qualified bidders able to offer service meeting
the Commission's requirements then consumers would ultimately be
harmed. In the Phase II Auction Order, the Commission required bidders
to submit with their short-form applications any information required
to establish their eligibility for weights adopted by the Commission.
Now that the Commission has adopted weights for the performance and
latency tiers, it is persuaded that in some circumstances it may serve
the public interest to require potential bidders to submit evidence
that demonstrates that they can meet the service requirements
associated with the tiers in which they intend to bid. The Commission
concludes that such an approach is likely to provide further assurance
that Phase II auction support will be awarded to qualified bidders. In
a future Commission-level public notice after opportunity for further
comment, the Commission intends to: (1) specify what evidence or other
information must be submitted, (2) establish the conditions for when
such information must be submitted, (3) adopt the applicable standards
that bidders must demonstrate, (4) set procedures for reviewing and
validating the submitted information, and (5) adopt any additional
penalties if capabilities are misrepresented.
28. While the Commission already requires that potential bidders
make certain showings in their short-form applications, the Commission
is not persuaded by claims that this information will offer sufficient
[[Page 14471]]
assurance that potential bidders are qualified to meet the applicable
tier requirements in all circumstances. Instead, given the varying
capabilities of the technologies that the Commission expects bidders
will propose to use to meet their obligations, it concludes there may
be circumstances where it will serve the public interest for the
Commission to make an independent, objective decision regarding
potential bidders' capabilities and also require bidders to demonstrate
they have undergone the necessary due diligence to ensure they can meet
the applicable requirements before bidding in particular tiers. The
Commission also disagrees with claims that the technical showings it
requires in the long-form application will sufficiently address the
Commission's concerns because it will not have access to this
information until winning bidders have already been selected.
29. Finally, the Commission rejects suggestions that the Commission
intended to adopt the same eligibility process it adopted for the rural
broadband experiments or that the Commission would need to reconsider
the eligibility requirements it has already adopted in the Phase II
Auction Order to require potential bidders to submit additional
evidence in their short-form applications. Instead, the Commission made
clear that potential bidders would be required to submit any
information or documentation required to establish their eligibility
for bidding weights adopted by the Commission. Moreover, eligibility
considerations are different in the Phase II auction context than they
were for the rural broadband experiments. The intent of the rural
broadband experiments was to award support to discrete experiments. If
a bidder was found to be unqualified after being announced as a winning
bidder, the relevant service area would be made eligible for Phase II
if the Commission determined that the area remained unserved. By
contrast, one of the main objectives of the Phase II auction is to
maximize coverage. As the Commission explained above, selecting bidders
that are later determined to be unqualified will thwart this objective
because the areas included in the unqualified winning bid and other
areas covered by bids that would have otherwise been selected will lose
an opportunity to be served through the Phase II auction.
30. Although the Commission declines to adopt state-based
preferences or ceiling in the Connect America Phase II auction, it is
persuaded that it should reserve funding in the Remote Areas Fund for
any state that did not receive support equal to the funding declined in
the statewide election process, subject to the conditions described
below. The Commission continues to recognize the importance of
connecting consumers in areas that would have been reached had the
Phase II offer been accepted and to provide sufficient universal
service funds to do so. Accordingly, the Commission intends to observe
the outcome of the Phase II auction, and will adopt a process for the
Remote Areas Fund to ensure that states receive an equitable
distribution of funds. In order to ensure service is extended
expeditiously to areas not supported in the Phase II auction, the
Commission also reaffirms that the Commission will seek to commence the
Remote Areas Fund auction no later than one year after the commencement
of the Phase II auction.
31. Specifically, once the Commission has had the opportunity to
observe the results of the Phase II auction it will prioritize bids in
the Remote Areas Fund auction that are placed in such declined states
until it has awarded enough support to make up the difference between
the total Phase II declined support and the total support that was
awarded in the state by the Phase II auction, to the extent possible
based on bids placed, remaining eligible areas, and budget available.
To ensure that support is targeted to commercially reasonable bids, the
Commission anticipates that only bids that are at or below the reserve
price would be eligible for this preference. Any implementation details
will be adopted when the Commission finalizes the procedures for the
Remote Areas Fund auction after observing the outcome of the Phase II
auction.
32. The Commission acknowledges that this approach may mean that
some areas in declined states have to wait longer to get service than
if support was awarded through the Phase II auction. Nevertheless, on
balance the Commission concludes this approach serves the public
interest because it reasonably enables us to achieve its objectives by
first using the Phase II auction to maximize its budget by prioritizing
cost-effective bids and then targeting support to areas that remain
unserved in the Remote Areas Fund. Indeed, the areas where support has
been declined are, according to the Commission's cost model, lower cost
than the extremely high-cost areas that are eligible nationwide. While
it is possible that some areas that would have received support if the
Commission implemented preferences in the Phase II auction may be left
unserved after the Phase II auction, it is also possible that bidders
will be attracted to serve these lower-cost areas and will be awarded
support through the Phase II auction to the extent that they place
cost-effective bids when compared to the reserve price and bids
nationwide.
33. For these reasons, the Commission concludes that this approach
is preferable to adopting weights for the Phase II auction for states
where Phase II auction support was declined, or adopting other measures
like support thresholds, ceilings, or rankings in the Phase II auction.
Instead, the possibility that state preferences in the Phase II auction
could divert funding from more cost-effective and higher service
quality bids in the Phase II auction, and the added complexity they
would introduce to the Phase II auction, outweigh the potential
benefits. The Commission concludes that any inequitable distribution
issues would be better addressed after the Phase II auction, after
bidders have had the opportunity to place cost-effective competitive
bids in all states.
34. The Commission disagrees with commenters that argue that the
Commission should not implement any preferences for states where Phase
II model-based support was declined. Instead, the Commission has
acknowledged that an incumbent price cap carrier's decision to decline
Phase II model-based support does not diminish the Commission's
universal service obligation to connect consumers in areas that would
have been reached had the offer been accepted and to provide sufficient
universal service funds to do so. To the extent unserved areas remain
in declined states after cost-effective bids have been awarded in the
Phase II auction and bidders are willing to serve those areas with
support equal to or less than the relevant reserve price, the
Commission concludes that it is reasonable to spend at least as much
support through the Phase II and Remote Areas Fund auctions that the
Commission was willing to spend through the Phase II offer of support
to address a similar number of unserved consumers in these states. And
as the Commission explained above, it is using this approach as a
backstop, once it has had the opportunity to select bids based on cost-
effectiveness and service quality through the Phase II auction.
35. The Commission is not persuaded that it should adopt weights or
any other kind of preferences for states where the state has either
provided state broadband funding or has committed to co-invest funds
for winning Phase II auction bids, or where the state is a net
[[Page 14472]]
payer to the universal service fund. First, as noted above, these
proposals would add additional complexity to the Phase II auction, both
for the Commission in designing and executing an auction that would
incorporate these preferences and for bidders that may face difficulty
in putting together a cost-effective bid that accounts for such
preferences. Second, if a state has implemented a broadband program,
Phase II bidders could use those funds to supplement the funds they are
seeking from the federal Connect America program, thereby lowering
their bids so that they are more competitive. The state's contribution
to a project will already effectively lower the amount of support a
bidder needs from the federal universal service fund. Third, the
Commission's universal service programs are designed to target areas
where there is not a business case for service providers to offer
reasonably comparable services at reasonably comparable rates. By
virtue of the geography of each state, some states have more of these
areas than others and thus require more support to achieve the
Commission's universal service objectives. It would contradict the
Commission's statutory responsibility to connect all Americans with
reasonably comparable services if the Commission were to target federal
universal service support to certain states for the sole reason that
their ratepayers contribute more into the universal service fund than
the states receive from all disbursement programs in the aggregate.
36. The Commission is not convinced that it should set up a
separate mechanism to allocate support directly to declined states--
either in lieu of those states participating in the Phase II auction or
for those states that do not receive a certain level of support in the
Phase II auction--or work in partnership with the states to choose
winning projects based on specified criteria. Not only would this cause
further delay in getting support to those areas because the Commission
would need to establish rules for a new mechanism, it would also
contradict its decision to allocate unclaimed Phase II support using
market-based mechanisms--the Phase II auction and the Remote Areas Fund
auction. For all the reasons explained above, the Commission continues
to conclude that requiring bidders to compete for support rather than
using more subjective measures to select awardees will lead to a more
efficient use of its finite budget.
37. While the Commission acknowledges that it conditionally waived
the Phase II auction program rules to make available up to an amount of
support that is equivalent to the amount of support Verizon declined in
New York to be allocated in partnership with New York's New NY
Broadband Program, the Commission did not guarantee that carriers in
New York would be awarded the full $170.4 million if winning bidders
were not authorized for this amount by the Commission in coordination
with New York's program. Moreover, such support will be allocated to
service providers rather than directly to the state. Such bidders are
required to compete for funds through New York's broadband program and
will only be eligible to be authorized for Phase II support if they are
selected as winning bidders and if New York commits a matching amount
of support at the minimum. The Commission also finds that the public
interest considerations in that context are different than the
considerations here. The Commission's decision to allocate up to $170.4
million in coordination with New York's program was premised on the
fact that New York had committed a significant amount of state support
and had already established a program that is compatible with the
objectives of Connect America Phase II and that will lead to faster
build out and potentially higher speeds than if the Commission had
waited for the Phase II auction to allocate the support. Working in
partnership with New York also meant that the Commission could
eliminate potential overlaps between the two programs that could
otherwise thwart the Commission's Connect America objectives. No other
state has demonstrated that they have adopted a similar program that
would achieve the same or similar public interest benefits.
38. While the Commission remains committed to promoting deployment
on Tribal lands, it declines to adopt a Tribal-specific preference for
Tribal entities or entities choosing to serve Tribal lands in the Phase
II auction. For the reasons described above, the Commission concludes
that it serves the public interest to award Phase II support to the
most cost-effective bids, subject to the performance and latency
weights it adopts above. The Commission's decision to score a bid's
cost-effectiveness relative to the reserve price will ensure that
service providers that place cost-effective bids that commit to serve
Tribal lands will be competitive. Furthermore, the Connect America Cost
Model used to set reserve prices already takes into consideration many
factors causing varying deployment costs. With this approach, the
auction is able to use a market-based mechanism to award support for
the purposes of connecting all consumers, including those on Tribal
lands. The Commission's action today does not preclude us from adopting
preferences for Tribal entities or entities serving Tribal lands in the
Remote Areas Fund auction if Tribal lands remain unserved after the
Phase II auction and after the Commission has had the opportunity to
observe the outcome of the Phase II auction.
39. It is unclear at this time what the effect of a Tribal bidding
credit would be given the Commission's decision to adopt weights for
service and latency tiers. The Commission concludes that it serves the
public interest to maximize its budget by first determining whether the
Commission's recent policy decisions will result in cost-effective
competitive bids on Tribal lands in the Phase II auction. If not, the
Commission will be able to observe bidders' behavior in the Phase II
auction to determine how to best implement a targeted preference that
will encourage deployment on Tribal lands that remain unserved.
40. The Commission is not persuaded that Tribal governments should
instead select the service providers that will be serving Tribal lands
or that Tribally-owned or -controlled carriers should have the right of
first refusal. The Commission's paramount goal must be to maximize the
value of the universal service dollars it is spending on behalf of
consumers--including those on Tribal lands--and creating artificial
barriers to competing for support or deploying service on Tribal lands
will only serve to delay the build out of high-quality services that
rural Americans on Tribal lands want and need. Such an approach would
be contrary to the Commission's decision to conduct a competitive
bidding process in these areas to select service providers that will
efficiently use support to offer reasonably comparable services.
Moreover, eligible Tribally-owned or -controlled carriers will have the
opportunity to participate in the Phase II auction and potentially win
support if they place competitive bids.
41. The Commission concludes that it would not serve the public
interest to adopt alternative interim service milestones for non-
terrestrial service providers or service providers that already have
deployed the infrastructure they intend to use to fulfill their Phase
II obligations. The Commission expects that determining whether a
recipient has sufficiently built out its network and thus would be
subject to the alternative milestones would be a subjective and
possibly time-consuming fact-specific inquiry. Also, tracking and
verifying different milestones for a subset of Phase II auction
recipients that
[[Page 14473]]
are based on the timing of consumer requests would complicate the
Commission and USAC's oversight responsibilities. Additionally,
subjecting such providers to more aggressive interim milestones could
potentially undermine both their incentives to participate in the Phase
II auction and their willingness to take steps to deploy facilities
prior to being awarded Phase II auction support.
42. The Commission concludes that these considerations outweigh the
public interest benefits of the potential that in some circumstances
recipients will offer the required services faster if they have to meet
more aggressive milestones. Indeed, carriers that have deployed
infrastructure already have an incentive to meet their obligations
quickly. First, carriers will want to supplement universal service
support with customer revenue. Second, Phase II auction recipients are
required to maintain an open and renewed letter of credit only until
they have certified they have met their 100 percent service milestone
and that certification has been verified. As a result, Phase II auction
recipients may choose to accelerate the rate at which they offer the
required services so that they can close out their letter of credit
sooner.
III. Order on Reconsideration
43. In this Order on Reconsideration the Commission considers
several petitions for reconsideration of decisions made in the Phase II
Auction Order. First, the Commission denies a petition for
reconsideration of its decision to score bids relative to the reserve
price. Second, the Commission grants a petition for reconsideration of
its decision to retain the option to re-auction certain areas served by
high latency bidders if a set subscription rate is not met. Finally,
the Commission grants a petition for reconsideration of its decision to
require bidders in the Above-Baseline and Gigabit performance tiers to
offer an unlimited monthly usage allowance.
44. Discussion. The Commission declines to reconsider the decision
to score bids relative to the applicable reserve price. While one of
the Commission's objectives is to maximize the number of locations that
are served with its finite budget and ranking bids based on the dollar
per location would achieve that goal, the Commission has also made
clear that it is focused on adopting an auction design that balances
this objective with other goals, including efficiently and effectively
allocating support among the states. The Commission concludes that
ranking bids relative to the reserve price reasonably balances these
objectives.
45. As the Commission explained in the Phase II Auction Order, it
made the decision to adopt this bid-to-reserve price ratio methodology
to prevent support from disproportionately flowing to those states
where the cost to serve per location is, relatively speaking, lower
than other states. It is the Commission's statutory duty to support
universal service, which includes ``[c]onsumers in all regions of the
Nation,'' not just those living in denser areas. By ranking bids
relative to the reserve price, the Commission will be providing an
opportunity for bidders across the country to make competitive bids
while also working to maximize its available funds by awarding support
to the most cost-effective bids nationwide. Awarding support to those
areas where there are more locations might mean that the Commission
would get ``more bang for the buck'' by serving more locations with its
budget, but that approach might also preclude us from taking advantage
of efficiencies in cases where service providers are able to serve
areas with fewer locations but with support that is far below the
applicable reserve price. While the Commission acknowledges that it
could instead choose to award support to denser areas in the Phase II
auction and address the remaining areas in the Remote Areas Fund
auction, it concludes that on balance the public interest will be
served by giving consumers nationwide the opportunity to be served
sooner if cost-effective bids are placed in those areas. The Commission
notes that its decision to cap reserve prices for extremely high-cost
areas will help ensure that its budget is not disproportionately
diverted to these extremely high-cost areas. Support will only be
awarded to service providers that can make a business case to serve
these areas with support below the capped amount and that submit cost-
effective bids relative to other bids nationwide.
46. The Commission reconsiders the Commission's decision with
regard to re-auctioning areas served by high latency bidders where
there is low subscribership. Instead, all authorized Phase II auction
recipients will have a full 10-year term of support if they comply with
the terms and conditions of Phase II support. While the Commission had
adopted the subscriber standard to give high latency providers
something objective and quantifiable that they could track to determine
if the areas they serve would be placed in the Phase III auction, after
further reflection, the Commission is persuaded that this approach does
not necessarily reflect the quality of that service or the value to
consumers.
47. First, the Commission agrees that it may be difficult for high
latency service providers to obtain enough subscribers to meet the 35
percent threshold given that by the end of the third year of support,
Phase II auction recipients will only be required to offer service to
40 percent of the required number of locations and may not have focused
on adoption efforts while working on deploying their networks. And even
if the Commission were to push this option to later in the support
term, it would be difficult to determine an appropriate timeframe at
this point without knowing the timing for any subsequent auctions.
Second, consumers may decide not to subscribe to a service for any
number of reasons, and the Commission is persuaded by comments that
suggest that many of the factors that are related to low adoption are
likely to be present in more rural high-cost areas of the country.
48. While commenters suggest that they have had success in
encouraging broadband adoption in high-cost areas, they do not address
the Commission's timing concerns. Moreover, such a general statement
about their success does not provide us with adequate assurance that
high latency providers would have the same experience in the areas they
are awarded support absent service quality issues. In fact, if the
Commission uses a low adoption rate as the measure to determine if
service is meeting consumers' needs, it would seem to follow that the
Commission should also re-auction areas served by low latency service
providers that have low subscribership. For these reasons, the
Commission concludes that subscribership is not an appropriate measure
for determining whether a high latency service is meeting the needs of
consumers.
49. The Commission is also sympathetic to claims that even if it
were to come up with an alternative objective and quantifiable
standard, by simply retaining the option to shorten a high latency
service provider's support term it will create uncertainty for such
bidders. The Commission would be asking high latency providers to
commit significant resources to deploy at a minimum 40 percent of their
network while reserving the option to take away their support and
potentially fund a competitor in that same area. Such conditions may
mean that high latency providers will not participate in the auction or
will inflate their bids to compensate for the risk, which would
undermine the Commission's decision
[[Page 14474]]
to include high latency providers in the Phase II auction to maximize
the budget by increasing competition.
50. On balance, the Commission is persuaded that these harms
outweigh the public interest benefits of having the opportunity to
include areas served by high latency bidders in a subsequent auction
prior to the end of the 10-year term. As the Commission discussed
above, it acknowledges that some parties have significant concerns
about whether high latency services will meet the needs of consumers.
Nevertheless, the Commission concludes that the performance standards
it has adopted for high latency bidders will offer sufficient
protection to consumers living in areas served by a high latency
bidder. Moreover, as the Commission explains above, recognizing these
concerns it has adopted weights that give a preference to low latency
bids to achieve a reasonable balance between using its budget cost-
effectively to maximize the deployment of service to unserved consumers
with service quality. The Commission concludes that the potential that
it would undermine competition by retaining the option to re-auction
certain service areas could throw off this balance and potentially
thwart its ability to leverage the Phase II auction to further the
Commission's statutory objective of supporting reasonably comparable
services nationwide within its finite budget.
51. In order to encourage robust bidding, the Commission grants
Verizon's request for reconsideration of the Commission's prior
decision to require bidders in the Above-Baseline and Gigabit
performance tiers to offer an unlimited monthly usage allowance.
Instead, the Commission will require bidders in these tiers to offer a
monthly usage allowance of at least 2 terabytes (TB) per month.
52. As Verizon explains, a requirement of unlimited data could
discourage bidding on those tiers, because a potential bidder would
have to factor in additional investments and operating expenses to
accommodate a small number of customers whose very high usage would be
responsible for a disproportionate share of demand. Rather than require
unlimited usage, Verizon argues that the Commission could set a very
high allowance, which would provide a greater usage allowance than the
baseline tier but still permit providers to address true outliers that
increase the cost of providing rural broadband service. The Commission
is persuaded by Verizon's argument that requiring bidders to offer
unlimited usage would raise the cost of providing higher performance
services in rural areas and could discourage bidding in these tiers.
53. Therefore, instead of requiring bidders in the Above-Baseline
and Gigabit performance tiers to offer unlimited data allowances, the
Commission will require bidders in these tiers to offer a monthly usage
allowance of at least 2 terabytes (TB) per month. The Commission finds
that a 2 TB usage allowance is sufficiently high to ensure that rural
America is not left behind, and will enable more bidders to offer
higher performance services in rural areas. Although Verizon originally
suggested that recent urban rate survey data shows that many urban
providers have usage limits for services of 100 Mbps or more that range
from 250 GB to 1,000 GB (1 TB) per month, it more recently suggested a
usage allowance of 1 TB per month. Verizon cited usage limits from last
years' urban rate survey data, and the Commission finds it reasonable
to adopt a higher usage limit for a 10-year term of support. A data
allowance of 250 GB was the lower end of the range for comparable
services from this year's urban rate survey data. The Commission
therefore disagrees with WISPA's suggestion that a usage tier of only
250 GB for the Above-Baseline tier is sufficient for a 10-year support
term. Nor does the Commission agree with WISPA's argument there should
not be any usage limits for the Gigabit tier. WISPA did not raise any
substantive arguments to counter Verizon's arguments about the
additional costs of requiring unlimited usage in high-cost areas. The
Commission is therefore persuaded that an unlimited usage cap could
impose additional costs on bidders that may discourage them from
offering services that exceed its Baseline performance requirements in
rural areas. As always, Phase II winners will be free to offer an array
of service plans, including those with unlimited usage.
IV. Procedural Matters
54. This document does not contain new information collection
requirements subject to the PRA. In addition, therefore, it does not
contain any new or modified information collection burden for small
business concerns with fewer than 25 employees, pursuant to the Small
Business Paperwork Relief Act of 2002, Public Law 107-198, see 44
U.S.C. 3506(c)(4).
55. As required by the Regulatory Flexibility Act of 1980 (RFA) as
amended, an Initial Regulatory Flexibility Analyses (IRFA) was
incorporated in the Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking adopted in
November 2011 (USF/ICC Transformation FNPRM, 76 FR 78384, December 16,
2011), the Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking adopted in July 2014
(Rural Broadband Experiments FNPRM, 79 FR 44352, July 31, 2014), and
the Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking adopted in May 2016 (Phase II
Auction FNPRM). The Commission sought written public comment on the
proposals in the USF/ICC Transformation FNPRM, the State Action FNPRM,
and the Phase II Auction FNPRM, including comment on the IRFAs. The
Commission did not receive any relevant comments in response to these
IRFAs. This Final Regulatory Flexibility Analysis (FRFA) conforms to
the RFA.
56. With this Report and Order and Order on Reconsideration
(Order), the Commission takes another step towards implementing the
Connect America Phase II (Phase II) auction in which service providers
will compete to receive support of up to $1.98 billion to offer voice
and broadband service in unserved high-cost areas. The decisions the
Commission makes in this Order aim to maximize the value the American
people will receive for the universal service dollars it spends,
balancing higher-quality services with cost efficiencies.
57. First, the Commission resolves issues raised in the Phase II
Auction Order FNPRM. The Commission adopts weights to compare bids
among the service performance and latency tiers adopted in the Phase II
Auction Order. Additionally, the Commission declines to adopt specific
preferences for certain states and Tribal lands in the Phase II auction
and decline to adopt alternative interim deployment obligations for a
subset of Phase II auction recipients. However, the Commission does
adopt preferences that will be implemented in the Remote Areas Fund
auction for states where the Phase II offer of model-based support was
declined, subject to conditions.
58. Second, the Commission also considers several petitions for
reconsideration of decisions made in the Phase II Auction Order. The
Commission denies a petition for reconsideration of the Commission's
decision to score bids relative to the reserve price and grant a
petition for reconsideration of the Commission's decision to retain the
option to re-auction certain areas served by high latency bidders if a
set subscription rate is not met.
59. The RFA directs agencies to provide a description of, and where
feasible, an estimate of the number of small entities that may be
affected by the proposed rules, if adopted. The RFA
[[Page 14475]]
generally defines the term ``small entity'' as having the same meaning
as the terms ``small business,'' ``small organization,'' and ``small
governmental jurisdiction.'' In addition, the term ``small business''
has the same meaning as the term ``small-business concern'' under the
Small Business Act. A small-business concern'' is one which: (1) Is
independently owned and operated; (2) is not dominant in its field of
operation; and (3) satisfies any additional criteria established by the
Small Business Administration (SBA).
60. Total Small Entities. The Commission's proposed action, if
implemented, may, over time, affect small entities that are not easily
categorized at present. The Commission therefore describes here, at the
outset, three comprehensive, statutory small entity size standards.
First, nationwide, there are a total of approximately 28.2 million
small businesses, according to the SBA, which represents 99.7% of all
businesses in the United States. In addition, a ``small organization''
is generally ``any not-for-profit enterprise which is independently
owned and operated and is not dominant in its field.'' Nationwide, as
of 2007, there were approximately 1,621,215 small organizations.
Finally, the term ``small governmental jurisdiction'' is defined
generally as ``governments of cities, towns, townships, villages,
school districts, or special districts, with a population of less than
fifty thousand.'' Census Bureau data for 2011 indicate that there were
90,056 local governmental jurisdictions in the United States. The
Commission estimates that, of this total, as many as 89,327 entities
may qualify as ``small governmental jurisdictions.'' Thus, the
Commission estimates that most governmental jurisdictions are small.
61. The Report and Order and Order on Reconsideration do not impose
any specific reporting, recordkeeping, or compliance requirements for
entities, including small entities. Instead, the Report and Order
adopts or declines to adopt measures that will affect all bidders
participating in the Phase II auction. For example, the Report and
Order adopts weights for the Phase II auction technology-neutral
service and latency tiers, and indicates that the Commission will seek
comment on requiring potential bidders to establish their eligibility
for such weights. The Report and Order declines to take further action
to give a preference to certain states, Tribal bidders, or other types
of bids in the Phase II auction. However, the Report and Order does
adopt a preference for certain states in the Remote Areas Fund auction
where the Phase II offer of model-based support was declined, subject
to conditions. The Report and Order also declines to subject entities
that have already deployed a network capable of meeting their Phase II
obligations to different interim build-out milestones than the interim
build-out milestones that were adopted in the Phase II Auction Order.
62. The Order on Reconsideration declines to reconsider the
Commission's decision to score bids relative to the reserve price by
instead ranking bids on a dollar-per-location basis. In the Order on
Reconsideration the Commission also decides that all Phase II auction
recipients will have a 10-year support term, thereby reconsidering the
Commission's decision to retain the option to shorten the support term
of certain high latency bidders that are unable to meet a set
subscribership threshold.
63. The RFA requires an agency to describe any significant
alternatives that it has considered in reaching its proposed approach,
which may include (among others) the following four alternatives: (1)
The establishment of differing compliance or reporting requirements or
timetables that take into account the resources available to small
entities; (2) the clarification, consolidation, or simplification of
compliance or reporting requirements under the rule for small entities;
(3) the use of performance, rather than design, standards; and (4) an
exemption from coverage of the rule, or any part thereof, for small
entities. The Commission has considered all of these factors subsequent
to receiving substantive comments from the public and potentially
affected entities. The Commission has considered the economic impact on
small entities, as identified in comments filed in response to the USF/
ICC Transformation FNPRM, the Rural Broadband Experiments FNPRM and the
Phase II Auction FNRPM and their IRFAs, in reaching its final
conclusions and taking action in this proceeding.
64. Generally, the decisions that the Commission makes in this
Order will apply in equal force to all Phase II auction bidders,
including small bidders. Thus, the decisions made in this Order
generally do not impose unique burdens or benefits on small bidders.
For example, the Commission's decision to adopt weights for the
performance and latency tiers that will not grant an absolute
preference to any kind of service is unlikely to uniquely impact small
bidders, but it is likely to help maximize participation by making it
possible for all entities, including small entities, to be competitive
if they place a cost-effective bid. Additionally, like all bidders in
the Phase II auction, to the extent smaller bidders choose to bid in
less populated areas, they may benefit from the Commission's decision
to retain a bid ranking method that will score bids relative to the
applicable reserve price rather than a dollar per location basis.
65. In the Order, the Commission does decline to adopt proposals
for other weights or preferences in the Phase II auction, including a
preference specifically for small entities. The Commission concludes
that such an approach would not further its objective of maximizing the
effectiveness of its funds to serve consumers nationwide. Nevertheless,
recognizing the important role that small entities can play in bringing
voice and broadband services to unserved consumers, the Commission has
already adopted specific eligibility requirements for the Phase II
auction in an effort to facilitate the participation of small entities.
66. The Commission also indicates in the Order that it is persuaded
that in some circumstances it may serve the public interest to require
potential bidders to submit evidence that demonstrates that they can
meet the service requirements associated with the tiers in which they
will bid in their short-form applications. The Commission will seek
comment on this issue and will consider the unique challenges faced by
small entities in submitting any required information.
V. Ordering Clauses
67. Accordingly, it is ordered, pursuant to the authority contained
in sections 4(i), 214, 254, 303(r), 403, and 405 of the Communications
Act of 1934, as amended, 47 U.S.C. 154(i), 214, 254, 303(r), 403, and
405, and sections 1.1, 1.427, and 1.429 of the Commission's rules, 47
CFR 1.1, 1.427, and 1.429, that this Report and Order and Order on
Reconsideration is adopted, effective thirty (30) days after
publication of the text or summary thereof in the Federal Register. It
is the Commission's intention in adopting these rules that if any of
the rules that the Commission retains, modifies or adopts herein, or
the application thereof to any person or circumstance, are held to be
unlawful, the remaining portions of the rules not deemed unlawful, and
the application of such rules to other persons or circumstances, shall
remain in effect to the fullest extent permitted by law.
68. It is further ordered that, pursuant to section 1.429 of the
Commission's rules, 47 CFR 1.429 the Petition for Reconsideration filed
by Verizon on
[[Page 14476]]
August 8, 2016 is denied in part to the extent described herein.
69. It is further ordered that, pursuant to section 1.429 of the
Commission's rules, 47 CFR 1.429 the Petition for Reconsideration filed
by ViaSat, Inc. on August 8, 2016 is granted in part to the extent
described herein.
70. It is further ordered that the Commission shall send a copy of
this Report and Order to Congress and the Government Accountability
Office pursuant to the Congressional Review Act, see 5 U.S.C.
801(a)(1)(A).
Federal Communications Commission.
Marlene H. Dortch,
Secretary.
[FR Doc. 2017-05468 Filed 3-20-17; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6712-01-P