United States v. Charter Communications, Inc., et al.; Proposed Final Judgment and Competitive Impact Statement, 30550-30565 [2016-11562]
Download as PDF
jstallworth on DSK7TPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
30550
Federal Register / Vol. 81, No. 95 / Tuesday, May 17, 2016 / Notices
Lines, Inv. No. 337–TA–360, USITC
Pub. No. 2843 (December 1994)
(Commission Opinion).
If the Commission contemplates some
form of remedy, it must consider the
effects of that remedy upon the public
interest. The factors the Commission
will consider include the effect that an
exclusion order and/or cease and desist
orders would have on (1) the public
health and welfare, (2) competitive
conditions in the U.S. economy, (3) U.S.
production of articles that are like or
directly competitive with those that are
subject to investigation, and (4) U.S.
consumers. The Commission is
therefore interested in receiving written
submissions that address the
aforementioned public interest factors
in the context of this investigation.
If the Commission orders some form
of remedy, the U.S. Trade
Representative, as delegated by the
President, has 60 days to approve or
disapprove the Commission’s action.
See Presidential Memorandum of July
21, 2005. 70 FR 43251 (July 26, 2005).
During this period, the subject articles
would be entitled to enter the United
States under bond, in an amount
determined by the Commission and
prescribed by the Secretary of the
Treasury. The Commission is therefore
interested in receiving submissions
concerning the amount of the bond that
should be imposed if a remedy is
ordered.
Written Submissions: The parties to
the investigation are requested to file
written submissions on the issues
identified in this notice. Parties to the
investigation, interested government
agencies, and any other interested
parties are encouraged to file written
submissions on the issues of remedy,
the public interest, and bonding. Such
submissions should address the
recommended determination by the ALJ
on remedy and bonding. Complainants
and the IA are requested to submit
proposed remedial orders for the
Commission’s consideration.
Complainants are also requested to state
the date that the patents expire and the
HTSUS numbers under which the
accused products are imported.
Complainants are further requested to
supply the names of known importers of
the Umicore products at issue in this
investigation. The written submissions
and proposed remedial orders must be
filed no later than close of business on
May 23, 2016. Reply submissions must
be filed no later than the close of
business on June 2, 2016. Opening
submissions are limited to 50 pages.
Reply submissions are limited to 25
pages. Such submissions should address
the ALJ’s recommended determinations
VerDate Sep<11>2014
15:32 May 16, 2016
Jkt 238001
on remedy and bonding. No further
submissions on any of these issues will
be permitted unless otherwise ordered
by the Commission.
Persons filing written submissions
must file the original document
electronically on or before the deadlines
stated above and submit eight true paper
copies to the Office of the Secretary by
noon the next day pursuant to section
210.4(f) of the Commission’s Rules of
Practice and Procedure (19 CFR
210.4(f)). Submissions should refer to
the investigation number (‘‘Inv. No.
337–TA–951’’) in a prominent place on
the cover page and/or the first page. (See
Handbook for Electronic Filing
Procedures, https://www.usitc.gov/
secretary/fed_reg_notices/rules/
handbook_on_electronic_filing.pdf).
Persons with questions regarding filing
should contact the Secretary (202–205–
2000).
Any person desiring to submit a
document to the Commission in
confidence must request confidential
treatment. All such requests should be
directed to the Secretary to the
Commission and must include a full
statement of the reasons why the
Commission should grant such
treatment. See 19 CFR 201.6. Documents
for which confidential treatment by the
Commission is properly sought will be
treated accordingly. A redacted nonconfidential version of the document
must also be filed simultaneously with
any confidential filing. All nonconfidential written submissions will be
available for public inspection at the
Office of the Secretary and on EDIS.
The authority for the Commission’s
determination is contained in section
337 of the Tariff Act of 1930, as
amended (19 U.S.C. 1337), and in part
210 of the Commission’s Rules of
Practice and Procedure (19 CFR part
210).
Final Judgment, Stipulation, and
Competitive Impact Statement have
been filed with the United States
District Court for the District of
Columbia in United States of America v.
Charter Communications, Inc., et al.,
Civil Action No. 16–cv–00759. On April
25, 2016, the United States filed a
Complaint alleging that Charter
Communications, Inc.’s proposed
acquisitions of Time Warner Cable Inc.
and Bright House Networks, LLC would
violate Section 7 of the Clayton Act, 15
U.S.C. 18. The proposed Final
Judgment, filed at the same time as the
Complaint, forbids the merged company
from engaging in certain conduct that
could make it more difficult for
competing online video distributors
(OVDs) to obtain programming content.
Copies of the Complaint, proposed
Final Judgment, and Competitive Impact
Statement are available for inspection
on the Antitrust Division’s Web site at
https://www.justice.gov/atr and at the
Office of the Clerk of the United States
District Court for the District of
Columbia. Copies of these materials may
be obtained from the Antitrust Division
upon request and payment of the
copying fee set by Department of Justice
regulations.
Public comment is invited within 60
days of the date of this notice. Such
comments, including the name of the
submitter, and responses thereto, will be
posted on the Antitrust Division’s Web
site, filed with the Court, and, under
certain circumstances, published in the
Federal Register. Comments should be
directed to Scott A. Scheele, Chief,
Telecommunications and Media
Enforcement Section, Antitrust
Division, Department of Justice, 450
Fifth Street NW., Suite 7000,
Washington, DC 20530 (telephone: 202–
616–5924).
By order of the Commission.
Issued: May 11, 2016.
Lisa R. Barton,
Secretary to the Commission.
Patricia A. Brink,
Director of Civil Enforcement.
[FR Doc. 2016–11563 Filed 5–16–16; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 7020–02–P
DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE
Antitrust Division
United States v. Charter
Communications, Inc., et al.; Proposed
Final Judgment and Competitive
Impact Statement
Notice is hereby given pursuant to the
Antitrust Procedures and Penalties Act,
15 U.S.C. 16(b)–(h), that a proposed
PO 00000
Frm 00036
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT
FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA
United States of America, Department of
Justice, Antitrust Division, 450 5th Street
N.W., Suite 7000, Washington, DC, 20530,
Plaintiff, v., Charter Communications, Inc.,
400 Atlantic Street, Stamford, CT 06901,
Time Warner Cable Inc., 60 Columbus Circle,
New York, NY 10023, Advance/Newhouse
Partnership, 5823 Widewaters Parkway, East
Syracuse, NY 13057, and, Bright House
Networks, LLC, 5823 Widewaters Parkway,
East Syracuse, NY 13057, Defendants.
Case No.: 1:16–cv–00759
Judge: Royce C. Lamberth
Filed: 04/25/2016
E:\FR\FM\17MYN1.SGM
17MYN1
Federal Register / Vol. 81, No. 95 / Tuesday, May 17, 2016 / Notices
COMPLAINT
The United States of America, acting
under the direction of the Attorney
General of the United States, brings this
civil antitrust action to enjoin the
proposed combination of Charter
Communications, Inc. (‘‘Charter’’), Time
Warner Cable Inc. (‘‘TWC’’), and
Advance/Newhouse Partnership’s
(‘‘Advance/Newhouse’’) subsidiary,
Bright House Networks, LLC (‘‘BHN’’)
(collectively referred to herein as ‘‘New
Charter’’), which would create the
second-largest cable company and the
third-largest multi-channel video
distributor in the United States.
jstallworth on DSK7TPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
I. INTRODUCTION
1. Online video programming
distributors (‘‘OVDs’’) are beginning to
revolutionize the way Americans
receive and experience video content.
With access to an adequate Internet
connection, consumers can now choose
among a number of OVDs to access
collections of movies and television
shows, including original content, at
any time and on a device of their
choosing. The early OVDs, such as
Netflix, Hulu, and Amazon, focused on
offering on-demand video to their
customers and have developed video
services that have already proven
popular. Several newer OVDs, including
DISH Network’s Sling TV and Sony’s
Playstation Vue, have introduced
services that offer live television
channels in addition to on-demand
content. And several television
networks, including CBS, HBO, and
Showtime, have launched OVD services
to distribute their own programming
over the Internet directly to subscribers.
Continued growth of OVDs promises to
deliver more competitive choices and a
greater ability for consumers to
customize their consumption of video
content to their individual viewing
preferences and budgets.
2. The emergence of OVDs threatens
to upend the competitive landscape. For
years, incumbent cable companies such
as Comcast, TWC, and Charter have
served the majority of American video
households. Although these companies
now face competition from the two
direct broadcast satellite (‘‘DBS’’)
providers, DirecTV and DISH Network,
and, in some areas, from telephone
companies (‘‘telcos’’) like AT&T and
Verizon that also offer video services, all
of these distributors—collectively
referred to as multichannel video
programming distributors (‘‘MVPDs’’)—
offer fairly similar products and pricing.
Most notably, all of these MVPDs sell
content to consumers primarily through
large and costly video bundles that
VerDate Sep<11>2014
15:32 May 16, 2016
Jkt 238001
include hundreds of channels of
programming that many customers
neither desire nor watch.
3. In order for an OVD to successfully
compete with the traditional MVPDs, it
needs both the ability to reach
consumers over the Internet and the
ability to obtain programming from
content providers that consumers will
want to watch. Importantly, incumbent
cable companies often can exert
significant influence over one or both of
these essential ingredients to an OVD’s
success, because they provide
broadband connectivity that OVDs need
to reach consumers and are also a
critical distribution channel for the
same video programmers that supply
OVDs with video content. To the extent
a transaction, such as the one at issue
here, enhances an MVPD’s ability or
incentive to restrain OVDs’ access to
either of these critical inputs, and thus
to prevent OVDs from becoming a
meaningful new competitive option,
consumers lose.
4. MVPDs have responded to the
emergence of OVDs in various ways.
Many MVPDs have sought to keep their
customers from migrating some or all of
their viewing to OVDs by taking steps to
make their services more attractive to
consumers, for example, by allowing
their subscribers to receive
programming over the Internet through
Web sites or apps and providing
expanded video-on-demand offerings.
But some MVPDs have sought to
restrain nascent OVD competition
directly by exercising their leverage over
video programmers to restrict the
programmers’ ability to license content
to OVDs. To this end, some MVPDs
have sought so-called Alternative
Distribution Means (‘‘ADM’’) clauses in
their programming contracts that
prohibit programmers from distributing
content online, or have placed
significant restrictions on online
distribution. No MVPD has sought and
obtained these restrictive ADMs as
frequently, or as successfully, as TWC.
5. The combination of TWC with
Charter and BHN will result in a larger
MVPD with a greater ability and
incentive to secure restrictions on
programmers that limit or foreclose
OVD access to important content. The
Defendants, along with other MVPDs
and OVDs, compete with one another as
buyers of video content and serve as
alternative distribution channels for
national video programmers to build
viewership scale. Since New Charter
would have nearly 60 percent more
subscribers than TWC standing alone,
the merger will make New Charter a
more vital distribution channel for these
video programmers than each of the
PO 00000
Frm 00037
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
30551
Defendants individually. Hence, as a
result of the merger, New Charter will
have greater bargaining leverage to insist
that video programmers limit their
distribution to OVDs.
6. In addition, with its much larger
subscriber base, New Charter would
gain significant additional benefits from
impeding OVD competition. Today,
Charter, TWC, and BHN each only act
to protect its own MVPD profits. After
the merger, however, New Charter
would act to protect the much larger
combined video revenues of all three
Defendants. That is, while prior to the
merger TWC has an incentive to obtain
restrictive contract clauses to protect its
$10.4 billion in video revenues, New
Charter would have a much larger
incentive to protect the Defendants’ over
$16 billion in aggregated video
revenues.
7. With more to gain from imposing
ADMs and other contractual restrictions
and with greater bargaining leverage
with programmers to insist on such
provisions, New Charter will be wellpositioned to restrain continued OVD
growth by limiting or foreclosing OVD
access to the video content that is vital
to their competitiveness. Accordingly,
the proposed combination of Charter,
TWC, and BHN is likely to substantially
lessen competition in the provision of
video programming distribution in
violation of Section 7 of the Clayton
Act, 15 U.S.C. 18, and should be
enjoined.
II. JURISDICTION AND VENUE
8. The United States brings this action
under Section 15 of the Clayton Act, as
amended, 15 U.S.C. 25, to prevent and
restrain Charter, TWC, and BHN from
violating Section 7 of the Clayton Act,
15 U.S.C. 18.
9. Defendants Charter, TWC, and BHN
all provide video distribution services to
programmers in the flow of interstate
commerce, distributing video
programming to millions of consumers
in numerous states within the United
States. Accordingly, Defendants’
activities substantially affect interstate
commerce. The Court has subject matter
jurisdiction over this action and these
Defendants pursuant to Section 15 of
the Clayton Act, as amended, 15 U.S.C.
25, and 28 U.S.C. 1331, 1337(a), and
1345.
10. Defendants have consented to
personal jurisdiction and venue in the
District of Columbia for the purposes of
this action.
III. THE PARTIES AND THE
PROPOSED TRANSACTION
11. Defendant Charter is a Delaware
corporation with headquarters in
E:\FR\FM\17MYN1.SGM
17MYN1
30552
Federal Register / Vol. 81, No. 95 / Tuesday, May 17, 2016 / Notices
headquarters in East Syracuse, New
York, and the sole owner of Defendant
BHN, a Delaware limited liability
company headquartered in East
Syracuse, New York. BHN is the sixthlargest cable company in the United
States and the ninth-largest MVPD. BHN
owns cable systems serving around 2
million video customers across six
states. In 2014, BHN generated total
revenues of around $3.7 billion,
approximately $1.5 billion of which
were derived from its video business.
14. On May 23, 2015, Charter, TWC,
and Advance/Newhouse entered into a
series of agreements that would
combine Charter, TWC, and BHN into a
single company, New Charter. Pursuant
to these agreements, (1) Charter and
TWC would merge in a transaction
valued at over $78 billion; and (2)
Charter would acquire BHN from
Advance/Newhouse in a transaction
valued at $10.4 billion. The combined
entity would have nearly 17.4 million
video subscribers across 41 states,
making it the second-largest cable
company and third-largest MVPD,
accounting for nearly 18% of all MVPD
subscribers in the United States.
16. Video programmers produce
themselves, or acquire from other
copyright holders, a collection of
professional, full-length programs and
movies. These video programmers then
typically aggregate this content into
branded networks (e.g., NBC, ESPN, or
The History Channel) to create a 24hour-per-day television service that is
attractive to consumers. Many of the
largest video programmers control the
rights to multiple networks. Except for
networks of purely local or regional
interest, the video programmers will
contract with video programming
distributors across the country to
distribute the content to consumers.
17. In order to acquire the rights to
distribute each network, video
programming distributors pay the video
programmer a license fee. Generally,
MVPDs and OVDs pay the video
programmer a monthly per-subscriber
fee. These license fees are an important
revenue stream for video programmers.
Most of the remainder of their revenues
comes from fees for advertisements
placed on their networks.
18. Video programmers rely on video
programming distributors to reach
consumers. Unless a video programmer
obtains carriage in the packages of video
programming distributors that reach a
sufficient number of consumers, the
programmers will be unable to earn
enough revenue in licensing or to attract
enough advertising revenue to generate
a return on their investments in content.
For this reason, video programmers
prefer to have as many video
programming distributors as possible
carry their networks, and particularly
seek out the largest MVPDs that reach
the most customers. If the programmer
is unable to agree on acceptable terms
with a particular distributor, the
programmer’s content will not be
available to that distributor’s customers.
This potential consequence gives the
largest MVPDs significant bargaining
leverage in their negotiations with
programmers.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
15:32 May 16, 2016
Jkt 238001
PO 00000
Frm 00038
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
IV. THE VIDEO PROGRAMMING
DISTRIBUTION INDUSTRY
15. There are two distinct levels to the
video programming distribution
industry. At the ‘‘upstream’’ level, video
programmers license their content to
video programming distributors—both
OVDs and traditional MVPDs including
Charter, TWC, and BHN. At the
‘‘downstream’’ level, the video
programming distributors then sell
subscriptions to various packages of that
content and deliver the content to
residential customers.
V. RELEVANT MARKET
19. The timely distribution of
professional, full-length video
programming to residential customers
(‘‘video programming distribution’’)
constitutes a relevant product market
and line of commerce under Section 7
of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. 18. Both
E:\FR\FM\17MYN1.SGM
17MYN1
EN17MY16.332
jstallworth on DSK7TPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
Stamford, Connecticut. With over 4.2
million video subscribers across 28
states, Charter is the third-largest cable
company in the United States (behind
Comcast and TWC) and the sixth-largest
MVPD in the nation. In 2014, Charter
reported total revenues of around $9.1
billion. Nearly 49% of those revenues,
around $4.4 billion, were derived from
Charter’s video business.
12. Defendant TWC is a New York
corporation with headquarters in New
York, New York. With over 10.8 million
video subscribers across 30 states, TWC
is the second-largest cable company in
the United States (behind only
Comcast), and the fourth-largest MVPD
in the country. In 2014, TWC reported
total revenues of approximately $22.8
billion. Around 45% of those revenues,
or about $10.4 billion, were derived
from TWC’s video business.
13. Defendant Advance/Newhouse is
a New York partnership with
Federal Register / Vol. 81, No. 95 / Tuesday, May 17, 2016 / Notices
30553
satellites. OVDs are available to any
consumer with Internet service
sufficient to deliver video of an
acceptable quality. In contrast, wirelinebased distributors such as cable
companies and telcos generally must
obtain a franchise from local, municipal,
or state authorities in order to construct
and operate a wireline network in a
specific area, and then build lines to
homes in that area. A consumer cannot
purchase video programming
distribution services from a wireline
distributor operating outside its
franchise area because the distributor
does not have the facilities to reach the
consumer’s home. Thus, although the
set of video programming distributors
able to offer service to individual
consumers’ residences is generally the
same within each local community, the
set can differ from one local community
to another.
22. Each local community whose
residents face the same competitive
choices in video programming
distribution comprises a local
geographic market and section of the
country under Section 7 of the Clayton
Act, 15 U.S.C. 18. A hypothetical
monopolist of video programming
distribution in any of these geographic
areas could profitably raise prices by a
small but significant, non-transitory
amount.
23. The specific geographic markets
relevant to this action are the numerous
local markets throughout the United
States shown in the map below where
either Charter, TWC, or BHN is the
incumbent cable operator.
In order to protect its profits in these
geographic markets, which cover around
48 million U.S. television households
across 41 states, New Charter will have
an incentive to prevent rival OVDs from
obtaining, or to raise the costs of those
rivals obtaining, programming for their
services. Because these OVD
competitors also serve homes outside
New Charter’s service areas, however,
other local markets may be affected,
with the anticompetitive effects of the
transaction likely extending to the
whole nation.
subscribers within their respective
service areas, often above 50 percent.
The DBS providers, DirecTV and DISH,
account for approximately one-third of
the video programming distribution
subscribers nationwide, although their
shares vary by local market. The telcos,
AT&T and Verizon, account for over 10
percent of video programming
distribution nationwide and have
successfully achieved penetration of up
to 40 percent in some areas, but their
video services remain limited to certain
local markets and are unavailable to
most American homes. In a handful of
areas, other providers called
‘‘overbuilders’’ have constructed an
additional wireline network to
residential consumers, offering another
competitive option for video and
broadband service. But these
overbuilders, including companies like
RCN and Google Fiber, are available in
very few communities, serving less than
two percent of U.S. television
households nationwide.
25. Although OVDs have acquired a
significant number of customers over
the last several years, they account for
only five percent of total video
programming distribution revenues.
Nevertheless, established distributors
such as Charter, TWC, and BHN view
OVDs as a growing competitive threat
and have taken steps to respond to OVD
entry.
VI. MARKET CONCENTRATION
24. The incumbent cable companies
typically have the highest share of
VerDate Sep<11>2014
15:32 May 16, 2016
Jkt 238001
PO 00000
Frm 00039
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
E:\FR\FM\17MYN1.SGM
17MYN1
EN17MY16.333
jstallworth on DSK7TPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
MVPDs and OVDs are participants in
this market.
20. Video programming distribution is
characterized by the aggregation and
delivery of professionally produced
content. This content includes scripted
and unscripted television shows, live
programming, sports, news, and movies
licensed from a mixture of broadcast
and cable networks, as well as from
movie studios. Video programming can
be viewed immediately by consumers,
whether on demand or as scheduled.
21. Consumers purchase video
programming distribution services from
among those distributors that can offer
such services directly to their home.
The DBS operators, DirecTV and DISH,
can reach almost any customer in the
continental United States who has an
unobstructed line of sight to their
30554
Federal Register / Vol. 81, No. 95 / Tuesday, May 17, 2016 / Notices
consumers are emerging as ‘‘cord
nevers’’ that do not seek out an MVPD
subscription in the first place. Large
cable companies such as Charter and
TWC, which rely on their video
businesses to deliver significant profit
margins, have observed these
developments with growing concern. In
numerous internal documents,
Defendants show a keen awareness of
the competitive threat that OVDs pose.
In fact, a TWC board presentation from
February 2014 illustrated the threat
posed by such emerging online
competitors as a meteor speeding
toward earth:
28. Because of the threat OVDs pose
to their video business, some MVPDs
have an incentive to engage in tactics
that would diminish OVDs’ ability to
compete. TWC, in particular, has
recognized that it can use its contracts
with video programmers to try and
foreclose OVD competitors from access
to valuable content. TWC has been the
most aggressive MVPD in the industry
in seeking and obtaining restrictive
contract provisions in its agreements
with programmers that limit the
programmer’s ability to license
programming to OVDs. Specifically,
TWC has used the leverage that comes
from its status as an important
distribution channel for many video
programmers to secure ADM provisions
that either prevent the programmer from
distributing its content online, or place
certain restrictions on such online
distribution. For example, some of
TWC’s ADMs prohibit any online
distribution for a certain period of time;
others prevent the programmers from
distributing their content through OVDs
that do not meet specific criteria that
can be difficult for OVDs to satisfy (e.g.,
requiring the OVD to include a
minimum number of programming
networks in its service).
29. Although they offer service to
residential customers in different local
areas, each of the Defendants serves as
an alternative distribution channel for
nationwide video programmers to
deliver their content to consumers and
to build national viewership scale.
Video programmers rely on traditional
MVPDs to provide licensing fees and to
build a large viewership base that is
attractive to advertisers. Post-merger,
New Charter will become one of the
largest MVPDs in the country and will
serve as a critical distributor for video
programmers, offering access to over 17
million customers spread across 41
states. As a result, New Charter will
have more leverage to demand that
video programmers agree to forego or
limit the licensing of programming to
OVDs.
30. In addition, New Charter will have
greater incentive to engage in conduct
designed to make OVDs less competitive
because the merged firm will be
significantly larger than any of the
Defendants individually. Because New
Charter will have far more subscribers,
it will also stand to lose more profits as
OVDs continue to take business from
traditional video distributors. Today,
jstallworth on DSK7TPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
VerDate Sep<11>2014
15:32 May 16, 2016
Jkt 238001
PO 00000
Frm 00040
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
E:\FR\FM\17MYN1.SGM
17MYN1
EN17MY16.334
26. Charter, TWC, and BHN compete
with DBS, overbuilder, and telco
providers by upgrading their existing
services, offering promotions and other
price discounts, and introducing new
product offerings. Consumers benefit
from this competition by receiving
better quality services, lower prices, and
more programming choices.
Competition between the incumbent
cable companies and these alternative
video providers has also fostered
innovation, including the development
of digital transmission, HD, and 4K
programming, and the introduction of
DVRs, video-on-demand, and ways to
view content on other devices or away
from home.
27. The continued development and
expansion of OVDs could unlock
additional competitive benefits. Today,
many consumers purchase OVD services
as a supplement to a traditional MVPD
subscription. But in light of expanding
OVD options, some consumers are
switching from larger, more expensive
MVPD bundles to slimmer and cheaper
bundles. A small number of consumers
are even ‘‘cutting the cord’’—cancelling
their MVPD subscription altogether and
relying solely on one or more OVDs to
receive content. And many younger
VII. ANTICOMPETITIVE EFFECTS
Federal Register / Vol. 81, No. 95 / Tuesday, May 17, 2016 / Notices
any conduct that Charter engages in to
harm OVDs would only benefit Charter
within its own service territory. After
the merger, New Charter will internalize
the combined benefits to Charter, TWC,
and BHN of harming OVDs and
therefore will have a greater incentive to
do so, and will be willing to offer more
consideration to video programmers to
obtain licensing restrictions.
31. Restrictions imposed on video
programmers by New Charter will likely
make it more difficult for OVDs to
obtain important content from
programmers in the future. In order to
comply with New Charter’s restrictions,
video programmers may have to
effectively cease providing certain
programming to an OVD altogether, or
may be obligated to impose burdensome
conditions on an OVD (such as the
requirement to include a minimum
number of programming networks in the
service). Such actions could negatively
affect OVDs’ business models and
undermine their ability to provide
robust video offerings that compete with
the offerings of traditional MVPDs. By
limiting OVDs’ access to content that is
important to their customers, the
competitiveness of OVDs will likely be
diminished and consumers will likely
receive lower-quality services and fewer
choices.
VIII. ENTRY
32. Entry or expansion of traditional
video programming distributors will not
be timely, likely, or sufficient to reverse
the competitive harm that would likely
result from the proposed merger of
Charter, TWC, and BHN. Entry and
expansion in the traditional video
programming distribution business is
difficult and time-consuming because it
requires an enormous upfront
investment to create distribution
infrastructure such as building out
wireline facilities or launching
satellites. Entry or expansion into a new
geographic area also typically requires
approval from one or more regulatory
bodies.
33. OVDs are less likely to enter or
expand to develop into significant
competitors if denied access to popular
content as a result of the proposed
transaction.
jstallworth on DSK7TPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
IX. VIOLATION ALLEGED
34. The United States hereby
incorporates paragraphs 1 through 33.
35. Defendants’ proposed
combination of Charter, TWC, and BHN
would likely substantially lessen
competition in the numerous geographic
markets for video programming
distribution identified above in
VerDate Sep<11>2014
15:32 May 16, 2016
Jkt 238001
violation of Section 7 of the Clayton
Act, 15 U.S.C. 18.
36. Unless enjoined, the proposed
transactions between Charter, TWC, and
Advance/Newhouse would likely have
the following anticompetitive effects,
among others:
a. competition in the development,
provision, and sale of video
programming distribution services in
each of the relevant geographic markets
will likely be substantially lessened;
b. prices for video programming
distribution services will likely increase
to levels above those that would prevail
absent the proposed transactions; and
c. innovation and quality of video
programming distribution services will
likely decrease to levels below those
that would prevail absent the proposed
transactions.
X. REQUESTED RELIEF
37. Plaintiff United States requests
that this Court:
a. adjudge and decree that the
proposed transactions violate Section 7
of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. 18;
b. preliminarily and permanently
enjoin the Defendants from carrying out
the proposed transactions, or from
entering into or carrying out any other
agreement, understanding, or plan that
would have the effect of bringing the
video distribution businesses of Charter,
TWC, and BHN under common
ownership or control;
c. award the United States its costs in
this action; and
d. award the United States such other
and further relief as may be just and
proper.
Dated: April 25, 2016.
Respectfully submitted,
For Plaintiff United States of America:
/s/ lllllllllllllllllll
Renata B. Hesse (D.C. Bar #466107).
Principal Deputy Assistant Attorney General.
/s/ lllllllllllllllllll
Patricia A. Brink,
Director of Civil Enforcement.
/s/ lllllllllllllllllll
Scott A. Scheele (D.C. Bar #429061),
Chief, Telecommunications & Media
Enforcement Section.
/s/ lllllllllllllllllll
Lawrence M. Frankel (D.C. Bar #441532),
Assistant Chief, Telecommunications &
Media Enforcement Section.
/s/ lllllllllllllllllll
Robert A. Lepore*,
Ruediger R. Schuett (D.C. Bar #501174),
Maureen Casey (D.C. Bar #415893),
Trial Attorneys, U.S. Department of Justice,
Antitrust Division, Telecommunications &
Media Enforcement Section, 450 Fifth Street
NW., Suite 7000, Washington, DC 20530,
Telephone: (202) 532–4928, Facsimile: (202)
PO 00000
Frm 00041
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
30555
514–6381, Email: Robert.Lepore@usdoj.gov,
*Attorney of Record
UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR
THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA
United States of America, Plaintiff, v.
Charter Communications, Inc., Time Warner
Cable Inc, Advance/Newhouse Partnership,
and Bright House Networks, LLC, Defendants.
Case No.: 1:16–cv–00759
Judge: Royce C. Lamberth
Filed: 05/10/2016
COMPETITIVE IMPACT STATEMENT
The United States of America
(‘‘United States’’), pursuant to Section
2(b) of the Antitrust Procedures and
Penalties Act (‘‘APPA’’ or ‘‘Tunney
Act’’), 15 U.S.C. 16(b)–(h), files this
Competitive Impact Statement relating
to the proposed Final Judgment
submitted for entry in this civil antitrust
proceeding.
I. NATURE AND PURPOSE OF THE
PROCEEDING
On May 23, 2015, Charter
Communications, Inc. (‘‘Charter’’) and
Time Warner Cable, Inc. (‘‘TWC’’), two
of the largest cable companies in the
United States, agreed to merge in a deal
valued at over $78 billion. In addition,
Charter and Advance/Newhouse
Partnership, which owns Bright House
Networks, LLC (‘‘BHN’’), announced
that Charter would acquire BHN for
$10.4 billion, conditional on the sale of
TWC to Charter. As a result of these
transactions, the combined company,
referred to as ‘‘New Charter,’’ will
become one of the largest providers of
pay television service in the United
States.
The United States filed a civil
antitrust Complaint on April 25, 2016,
seeking to enjoin the proposed
transactions because their likely effect
would be to lessen competition
substantially in numerous local markets
for the timely distribution of
professional, full-length video
programming to residential customers
(‘‘video programming distribution’’)
throughout the United States in
violation of Section 7 of the Clayton
Act, 15 U.S.C. 18. Specifically, the
Complaint alleges that the proposed
merger would increase the ability and
incentive of New Charter to use its
leverage with video programmers to
limit the access of online video
distributors (‘‘OVDs’’) to important
content. These OVDs are increasingly
offering meaningful competition to
cable companies like Charter, and the
loss of competition caused by the
proposed merger likely would result in
lower-quality services, fewer choices,
and higher prices for consumers, as well
E:\FR\FM\17MYN1.SGM
17MYN1
30556
Federal Register / Vol. 81, No. 95 / Tuesday, May 17, 2016 / Notices
in the Orlando and Tampa-St.
Petersburg, Florida areas. BHN is a
wholly-owned subsidiary of Advance/
Newhouse Partnership. Although the
Advance/Newhouse Partnership retains
the authority to manage BHN, it has
entered into agreements by which TWC
performs certain functions for BHN,
including the procurement of cable
programming. In 2014, BHN generated
total revenues of around $3.7 billion,
approximately $1.5 billion of which
were derived from its video business.
The proposed transactions combining
Charter, TWC, and BHN into New
Charter, as initially agreed to by the
Defendants on May 23, 2015, would
lessen competition substantially in
numerous local markets for video
programming distribution. These
transactions are the subject of the
Complaint and proposed Final
Judgment filed by the United States on
April 25, 2016.
FCC’s remedy is independent of the
proposed Final Judgment and not
subject to review in this proceeding.
1. Video Programmers
movies. These video programmers then
typically aggregate this content into
branded networks (e.g., NBC or The
History Channel) that provide a 24-hour
schedule that is attractive to consumers.
Large video programmers often own
multiple individual networks. For
instance, The Walt Disney Company
owns the ABC broadcast network as
involving the transfer of a telecommunications
license are in the ‘‘public interest, convenience, and
necessity.’’ 47 U.S.C. 310(d).
Video programmers produce
themselves, or acquire from other
copyright holders, a collection of
professional, full-length programs and
1 Under the Communications Act, the FCC has
jurisdiction to determine whether mergers
VerDate Sep<11>2014
15:32 May 16, 2016
Jkt 238001
II. DESCRIPTION OF THE EVENTS
GIVING RISE TO THE ALLEGED
VIOLATION
A. The Defendants and the Proposed
Merger
Charter is the third-largest cable
company in the United States, and the
sixth-largest multichannel video
programming distributor (‘‘MVPD’’)
overall. Charter owns cable systems
across 28 states, serving approximately
4.8 million residential broadband
customers and 4.2 million residential
video customers. Charter reported total
revenues of around $9.1 billion in 2014,
approximately $4.4 billion of which
were derived from Charter’s video
business.
TWC is the second-largest cable
company in the United States (behind
only Comcast Corp.), and the fourthlargest MVPD in the country. TWC’s
cable systems serve approximately 11.7
million residential broadband and 10.8
million residential video customers in
30 states. TWC reported total revenues
of approximately $22.8 billion in 2014,
around $10.4 billion of which were
derived from TWC’s video business.
BHN is the sixth-largest incumbent
cable company in the United States and
the ninth-largest MVPD overall. It owns
cable systems serving approximately 2
million video customers across six
states, the majority of whom are located
PO 00000
Frm 00042
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
B. The Structure of the Video
Programming Distribution Industry
The video programming distribution
industry operates at two distinct levels.
At the ‘‘upstream’’ level, video
programmers license their content to
video programming distributors—both
OVDs and traditional MVPDs including
Charter, TWC, and BHN. At the
‘‘downstream’’ level, the video
programming distributors then sell
subscriptions to various packages of that
content and deliver the content to
residential customers.
E:\FR\FM\17MYN1.SGM
17MYN1
EN17MY16.335
jstallworth on DSK7TPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
as reduced investment and less
innovation in this dynamic industry.
At the same time the Complaint was
filed, the United States also filed a
Stipulation and proposed Final
Judgment, which are designed to
eliminate the anticompetitive effects of
the proposed merger. Under the
proposed Final Judgment, which is
explained more fully below, the
Defendants will be prohibited from
using their bargaining leverage with
video programmers to inhibit the flow of
video content to OVDs. The proposed
Final Judgment will provide a prompt,
certain, and effective remedy for
consumers by preventing New Charter
from using its leverage over
programmers to harm competition. The
United States and the Defendants have
stipulated that the proposed Final
Judgment may be entered after
compliance with the APPA. Entry of the
proposed Final Judgment would
terminate this action, except that the
Court would retain jurisdiction to
construe, modify, or enforce the
provisions of the proposed Final
Judgment, and to punish and remedy
violations thereof.
The proposed merger was also subject
to review and approval by the Federal
Communications Commission (‘‘FCC’’).1
On May 5, 2016, the FCC adopted an
order approving the transactions subject
to certain conditions discussed below,
and that order was released publicly on
May 10, 2016. The Department and the
FCC coordinated closely in their
reviews of the proposed merger. The
Federal Register / Vol. 81, No. 95 / Tuesday, May 17, 2016 / Notices
well as many cable networks such as
ESPN and The Disney Channel.
In order to acquire the rights to
distribute each network, video
programming distributors pay the video
programmer a license fee, generally on
a per-subscriber basis. These license
fees are an important revenue stream for
video programmers. Most of the
remainder of their revenues comes from
fees for advertisements placed on their
networks.
Video programmers rely on video
programming distributors—both MVPDs
and OVDs—to reach consumers. Unless
a video programmer obtains carriage in
the packages of video programming
distributors that reach a sufficient
number of consumers, the programmers
will be unable to earn enough revenue
in licensing or to attract enough
advertising revenue to generate a return
on their investments in content. For this
reason, video programmers prefer to
have as many video programming
distributors as possible carry their
networks, and particularly seek out the
largest MVPDs that reach the most
customers. If the programmer is unable
to agree on acceptable terms with a
particular distributor, the programmer’s
content will not be available to that
distributor’s customers. This potential
consequence gives the largest MVPDs
significant bargaining leverage in their
negotiations with programmers.
jstallworth on DSK7TPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
2. Multichannel Video Programming
Distributors
Traditional video programming
distributors include incumbent cable
companies such as Charter and TWC;
direct broadcast satellite (‘‘DBS’’)
providers such as DirecTV and DISH
Network; telephone companies
(‘‘telcos’’) that offer video services such
as Verizon and AT&T; and overbuilders
such as Google Fiber and RCN.2 These
distributors are referred to collectively
as MVPDs. MVPDs typically offer
hundreds of channels of professional
video programming to residential
customers for a monthly subscription
fee.
3. Online Video Programming
Distributors
OVDs are relatively recent entrants
into the video programming distribution
market. They deliver a variety of live
and/or on-demand video programming
over the Internet, whether streamed to
Internet-connected televisions or other
devices, or downloaded for later
2 Overbuilders are providers who have
constructed an additional wired network to
residential consumers for offering video and
broadband service (i.e., they have ‘‘built over’’ the
cable and phone company networks).
VerDate Sep<11>2014
15:32 May 16, 2016
Jkt 238001
viewing. OVDs today include services
like Netflix, Hulu, Amazon Prime
Instant Video, and Sling TV, although,
as discussed in more detail below, their
content selection and business models
vary greatly. Unlike MVPDs, OVDs do
not own distribution facilities and are
dependent upon broadband Internet
access service providers, including
incumbent cable companies such as
Charter and TWC, for the delivery of
their content to viewers.
C. The Relevant Market and Market
Concentration
The Complaint alleges that video
programming distribution constitutes a
relevant product market and line of
commerce under Section 7 of the
Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. 18. The market
for video programming distribution
includes both traditional MVPDs and
their newer OVD rivals.
Consumers purchase video
programming distribution services from
among those distributors that can offer
such services directly to their home.
The DBS operators, DirecTV and DISH,
can reach almost any customer in the
continental United States who has an
unobstructed line of sight to their
satellites. OVDs are available to any
consumer with an Internet service
sufficient to deliver video of an
acceptable quality. In contrast, wirelinebased distributors such as cable
companies and telcos generally must
obtain a franchise from local, municipal,
or state authorities in order to construct
and operate a wireline network in a
specific area, and then build lines to
homes in that area. A consumer cannot
purchase video programming
distribution services from a wireline
distributor operating outside its
franchise area because the distributor
does not have the facilities to reach the
consumer’s home. Thus, although the
set of video programming distributors
able to offer service to individual
consumers’ residences is generally the
same within each local community, the
set can differ from one local community
to another.
According to the Complaint, each
local community whose residents face
the same competitive choices in video
programming distribution comprises a
geographic market and section of the
country under Section 7 of the Clayton
Act, 15 U.S.C. 18. The geographic
markets relevant to this action are the
numerous local markets throughout the
United States where either Charter,
TWC, or BHN is the incumbent cable
operator—an area encompassing 48
million U.S. television households
located across 41 states. However,
because OVDs typically offer services
PO 00000
Frm 00043
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
30557
nationwide, the Complaint alleges that
anticompetitive effects of the proposed
merger likely extend to the entire
United States.
The incumbent cable companies are
often the largest video distribution
provider in their respective local
territories; the Defendants’ market
shares, for example, exceed 50 percent
in many local markets in which they
operate. The DBS providers, DirecTV
and DISH Network, account for an
average of about one third of video
programming subscribers combined in
any given local market. The telcos,
including AT&T and Verizon, have
market shares as high as 40 percent in
the communities they have entered, but
they are only available in limited areas
and account for about 10 percent of
video programming customers
nationwide. Overbuilders such as
Google Fiber can also have moderately
high shares in particular local markets,
but their services are only available in
a small number of areas and they
account for fewer than two percent of
nationwide video programming
distribution subscribers.
Although OVDs have acquired a
significant number of customers over
the last several years, most of these
customers also purchase traditional
MVPD subscriptions. As a result, OVDs
currently have a small share of video
programming distribution market
revenues—likely around 5%.
D. Emerging Competition From OVDs in
the Relevant Market
1. OVD Business Models and
Participants
OVDs have developed a number of
different business models for delivering
content to consumers. Several OVDs,
including Netflix, Amazon Prime
Instant Video, and Hulu Plus, offer
‘‘subscription video on demand’’
(‘‘SVOD’’) services where consumers
typically obtain access to a wide library
of movies, past-season television shows,
and original content for a subscription
fee.3 In addition, some individual cable
programmers, such as CBS and HBO,
have begun offering their content
directly to consumers on an SVOD
basis. For example, HBO’s service,
branded HBO NOW, provides
subscribers who pay a monthly fee with
access to the same HBO content over the
Internet that they would receive through
a subscription to HBO as part of an
MVPD package.
In contrast to these SVOD providers,
a few OVDs have recently begun
3 Hulu also offers current-season content from
various television networks on an ad-supported
basis for no subscription fee.
E:\FR\FM\17MYN1.SGM
17MYN1
30558
Federal Register / Vol. 81, No. 95 / Tuesday, May 17, 2016 / Notices
jstallworth on DSK7TPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
offering MVPD-like bundles of live,
scheduled content to consumers over
the Internet. In early 2015, DISH
launched Sling TV, a monthly
subscription service that provides
customers access to many of the same
cable networks that are available
through traditional MVPDs. Sony has
launched a similar service called
PlayStation Vue. Unlike SVODs, these
‘‘virtual’’ MVPDs (‘‘vMVPDs’’) provide
customers the ability to watch live
sports and news programming, as well
as other scheduled entertainment
programming, at the same time it is
available on traditional MVPDs.
2. The Effects of OVD Development on
Traditional MVPDs
As OVDs have developed new
business models and obtained a wider
array of attractive video content, they
have started to become closer
substitutes for traditional MVPD
services. Although many consumers
treat OVD services as a complement to
traditional MVPD service—for example,
purchasing services from an SVOD like
Netflix to access past season content
and Netflix’s original content but
subscribing to an MVPD for live and
current-season content—some are
already using OVDs as substitutes for at
least a portion of their video
consumption. These consumers buy
smaller content packages from
traditional MVPDs, decline to take
certain premium channels, or purchase
fewer VOD offerings, and instead
substitute content from OVDs, a practice
known as ‘‘cord-shaving.’’ In addition, a
small, but growing number of MVPD
customers are ‘‘cutting the cable cord’’
completely, using one or more OVDs as
a replacement for their MVPD service.
Finally, some younger consumers are
emerging as ‘‘cord nevers’’ who do not
seek out an MVPD subscription in the
first place.
Absent interference from the
established MVPDs, OVDs are likely to
continue to grow, and to become
stronger competitors to MVPDs.
Moreover, to the extent that OVDs
continue to develop services that more
closely resemble those offered by
traditional MVPDs, such as the live
programming offered by vMVPDs or the
current season content offered by
certain SVODs, traditional MVPDs will
likely face greater substitution to OVD
services. To this end, the Defendants’
internal documents show that they have
typically been comparatively less
concerned about competition from
certain SVOD providers, like Netflix,
that do not offer live or current-season
programming, and more concerned by
the threat posed by vMVPDs like Sling
VerDate Sep<11>2014
15:32 May 16, 2016
Jkt 238001
TV and SVODs like HBO NOW that
offer current season content.
3. Traditional MVPDs’ Responses to the
Growth of OVDs
The Defendants and many other
MVPDs recognize the threat that the
growth of OVDs pose to their video
distribution businesses. Numerous
internal documents reflect the
Defendants’ assessment that OVDs are
growing quickly and pose a competitive
threat to traditional forms of video
programming distribution. MVPDs have
responded to this growth in various
ways. To keep their customers from
migrating some or all of their viewing to
OVDs, many MVPDs, including the
Defendants, have introduced new and
less expensive packages with smaller
numbers of channels, increased the
amount of content available on an ondemand basis, and made content
available to subscribers on devices other
than traditional cable set-top boxes. At
the same time, however, some MVPDs
have sought to restrain nascent OVD
competition directly by exercising their
leverage over video programmers to
restrict video programmers’ ability to
license content to OVDs. As alleged in
the Complaint, and explained in more
detail below, TWC has been an industry
leader in seeking such restrictions, and
the formation of New Charter will create
an entity with an increased ability and
incentive to do so.
E. The Anticompetitive Effects of the
Proposed Merger
Although Defendants do not compete
to provide video distribution services to
consumers in the same local geographic
markets, the Clayton Act is also
concerned with mergers that threaten to
reduce the number or quality of choices
available to consumers by increasing the
merging parties’ incentive or ability to
engage in conduct that would foreclose
competition.4 For example, a merger
may create, or substantially enhance,
the ability or incentive of the merged
firm to protect its market power by
denying or raising the price of an input
to the firm’s rivals.
As alleged in the Complaint, New
Charter will be significantly larger than
each of the Defendants individually,
and thus will have a greater incentive
4 See Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S.
294, 317 (1962) (noting that the Clayton Act
intended to make illegal ‘‘not only [] mergers
between actual competitors, but also [] vertical and
conglomerate mergers whose effect may tend to
lessen competition in any line of commerce in any
section of the country.’’); FTC v. Procter & Gamble
Co., 386 U.S. 568, 577 (1967) (‘‘All mergers are
within the reach of § 7, and all must be tested by
the same standard, whether they are classified as
horizontal, vertical, conglomerate.’’).
PO 00000
Frm 00044
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
and ability to use its bargaining power
with video programmers to protect its
market power in the local markets for
video programming distribution.
Specifically, following the merger, New
Charter will be the one of the largest
MVPDs in the country, with over 17
million subscribers in 41 states, and will
therefore be a critical distribution
channel for video programmers. The
Complaint alleges that this greater scale
will give New Charter more leverage to
demand that programmers agree to limit
their distribution to OVDs, enabling the
merged firm to increase barriers to entry
for OVDs or otherwise make OVDs less
competitive.
The Complaint also alleges that New
Charter will have increased incentive to
engage in such behavior because it will
stand to lose substantially more profits
than Charter, TWC, and BHN
individually if OVDs take business from
traditional MVPDs, and it will
internalize more of the benefits of
harming OVDs. The Defendants’ specific
means for foreclosing OVDs—ADM
clauses and other restrictive contracting
provisions—are discussed in more
detail below.
1. TWC Is the Industry Leader in
Imposing ADMs and Other Restrictive
Programming Clauses that Limit Video
Programmers’ Rights to License to
OVDs
Video programmers sign lengthy
licensing agreements with distributors
that establish the terms on which the
distributors will carry the programmers’
networks. Sometimes, these licensing
agreements include restrictions on the
other distributors to whom the
programmer may license content, or on
other ways the programmer may make
the content available to consumers. One
type of restriction is often referred to in
the industry as an ‘‘alternative
distribution means’’ (‘‘ADM’’) clause.
ADM clauses take many forms, and in
some cases can have significant
consequences for programmers’ ability
to license to OVDs. For example, some
ADMs prohibit a video programmer
from licensing content to OVDs for an
extended period of time after the
content is first aired on traditional
MVPDs—permanently blocking OVDs
from being able to offer current-season
content from those programmers. Other
ADMs prohibit the programmer from
licensing content to OVDs unless the
OVDs meet a number of strict (and
sometimes elaborate) criteria that can be
difficult to satisfy.5
5 For instance, an ADM in one MVPD’s contract
with a video programmer prohibited the
programmer from licensing to any OVD unless that
E:\FR\FM\17MYN1.SGM
17MYN1
Federal Register / Vol. 81, No. 95 / Tuesday, May 17, 2016 / Notices
jstallworth on DSK7TPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
TWC has been the most aggressive
MVPD at seeking and obtaining
restrictive ADM clauses in recent years.
The Department’s review of hundreds of
programming contracts and ordinary
course business documents revealed
that TWC has obtained numerous ADMs
that limit distribution to paid OVDs.
Other distributors, by contrast, have
rarely, if ever, sought or obtained such
clauses, or have only obtained ADMs
that are much less restrictive. TWC’s
success in seeking and obtaining ADMs
is likely attributable in part to its
bargaining leverage over video
programmers; although such
programmers might disfavor such
restrictions because they require the
programmer to forsake opportunities to
earn revenues from OVDs, they are more
likely to agree to a large MVPD such as
TWC’s demand to include them because
they do not want to lose access to
TWC’s millions of cable subscribers.
The Department’s investigation
further suggested that TWC may be the
most aggressive at obtaining such
clauses because, other than Comcast,
TWC has more to lose from the
expansion of OVDs than any other
traditional MVPD. Although Comcast
also has substantial video profits at risk,
it is prohibited from entering into or
enforcing any provisions that restrict
distribution to OVDs under the terms of
a consent decree entered in United
States v. Comcast Corp.6 By contrast,
distributors with fewer subscribers than
TWC have less to lose from the
expansion of OVDs, and, in some cases,
may actually support OVD expansion
because they make little or no profit
margin on their video distribution
businesses and would prefer to improve
the attractiveness of their broadband
Internet access services. Meanwhile, the
two DBS providers, DISH and DirecTV,
have historically been comparable to
TWC in size, but because of their
different distribution technology and
their customer demographics, may
perceive a lower threat from OVDs. In
fact, DISH is offering an OVD service of
its own—Sling TV—and DirecTV
recently announced plans to offer a
similar OVD service.
OVD offered a package that included thirty-five
channels, including at least two channels each from
three out of a list of six large video programmers.
6 See Final Judgment, United States et al. v.
Comcast et al., Civil Action No. 1:11cv–00106,
2011–2 Trade Cas. (CCH) ¶77,585, 2011 WL
5402137 (D.D.C. Sept. 1, 2011), available at https://
www.justice.gov/atr/case-document/file/492196/
download.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
15:32 May 16, 2016
Jkt 238001
2. The Proposed Transaction Increases
New Charter’s Ability and Incentive To
Obtain ADMs and Other Restrictive
Programming Clauses
The number and scope of the ADMs
that TWC obtained prior to the merger
suggests that TWC believes that these
ADM clauses are worth whatever
consideration it must provide video
programmers in return. After the
merger, New Charter, with over 17
million video subscribers in 41 states,
will have even more leverage than TWC
to demand that programmers agree to
ADMs. Given the importance of New
Charter as a distribution channel,
programmers will be less likely to risk
losing access to New Charter’s
considerable subscriber base—which is
almost 60 percent larger than TWC
alone—and will be more likely to accept
to New Charter’s demands. Moreover,
since New Charter will have far more
profits at risk from increased OVD
competition than Charter, TWC, or BHN
standing alone, it will be willing to
provide greater consideration to
programmers to obtain such clauses. As
a result, New Charter can be expected to
seek and obtain ADMs with more
programmers than TWC has to date, and
the ADMs are likely to be more
restrictive than TWC’s current ADM
provisions. As alleged in the Complaint,
such ADMs could negatively affect
OVDs’ business models and undermine
their ability to provide robust video
offerings that compete with the offerings
of traditional MVPDs. The weakening of
OVD competition will result in lowerquality services, fewer consumer
choices, and higher prices.
4. Entry Is Unlikely To Reverse the
Anticompetitive Effects of the Proposed
Merger
Successful entry into the traditional
video programming distribution
business is difficult and requires an
enormous upfront investment to create
a distribution infrastructure. As alleged
in the Complaint, additional entry into
wireline or DBS distribution is not
likely to be significant for the next
several years. Telcos have been willing
to incur some of the enormous costs to
modify their existing telephone
infrastructure to distribute video, and
will continue to do so, but only in
certain areas. Other new providers, such
as Google Fiber, are also expanding
services, but the time and expense
required to build to each new area
makes expansion slow. Therefore,
traditional MVPDs’ market shares are
likely to be fairly stable over the next
several years.
PO 00000
Frm 00045
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
30559
OVDs represent the most likely
prospect for successful and significant
competitive entry into the existing video
programming distribution market.
However, in addition to the other
barriers they face, OVDs must obtain
access to a sufficient amount of content
to become viable distribution
businesses, and the proposed merger
will likely increase that barrier to entry
even further.
III. EXPLANATION OF THE
PROPOSED FINAL JUDGMENT
The proposed Final Judgment ensures
that New Charter will not impede
competition by using programming
contracts to prevent the flow of content
to OVDs. The proposed Final Judgment
thereby protects consumers by
eliminating the likely anticompetitive
effects of the proposed merger alleged in
the Complaint.
A. The Proposed Final Judgment
Prohibits Defendants From Limiting
Distribution to OVDs Through
Restrictive Licensing Practices
As discussed above, certain types of
contract provisions, such as ADMs, can
have the purpose and effect of limiting
distribution to OVDs. However, not all
provisions that limit distribution are
anticompetitive. Reflecting this reality,
Sections IV.A and IV.B of the proposed
Final Judgment set forth broad
prohibitions on restrictive contracting
practices, while Section IV.C delineates
a narrowly tailored set of exceptions.
Taken together, these provisions ensure
that New Charter cannot use restrictive
contract terms to harm the development
of OVDs, but preserve programmers’
incentives to produce quality
programming and New Charter’s ability
to compete with other distributors to
obtain marquee content.
Section IV.A of the proposed Final
Judgment prohibits New Charter from
entering into or enforcing agreements
that forbid, limit, or create incentives to
limit the provision of video
programming to OVDs. This language
prevents New Charter from enforcing
the ADM provisions in current TWC
contracts, or from entering into new
provisions.
Section IV.B provides additional
detail as to the types of terms that could
create ‘‘incentives to limit’’ distribution
to OVDs. The Department’s
investigation revealed that TWC has
obtained ADM provisions for the
purpose of attempting to limit
distribution to OVDs. However, once
those agreements are prohibited, New
Charter could substitute ADMs with
more subtle types of contract provisions
that do not directly limit distribution to
E:\FR\FM\17MYN1.SGM
17MYN1
30560
Federal Register / Vol. 81, No. 95 / Tuesday, May 17, 2016 / Notices
jstallworth on DSK7TPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
OVDs, but make it financially
unattractive for video programmers to
license content to OVDs. For instance,
absent relief, New Charter could enter
into an agreement that permits a video
programmer to license content to an
OVD, but specifies that so licensing will
entitle New Charter to a massive license
fee discount. To prevent evasion of the
ban on ADMs, Section IV.B.1 clarifies
that such ‘‘penalty’’ provisions that
create incentives to limit distribution to
OVDs are not permitted.
Alternatively, New Charter could
enter into certain kinds of ‘‘most favored
nation’’ (‘‘MFN’’) provisions that are
designed to create incentives to limit
distribution to OVDs. Although MFN
provisions are ubiquitous in the
industry—for example, many MVPDs
use MFN provisions entitling the MVPD
to the lowest license fee that the
programmer offers to any other MVPD—
the Department’s investigation revealed
that some MVPDs were utilizing certain
provisions that, while referred to as
‘‘MFNs,’’ actually require much more
than equal treatment. Specifically, some
provisions, commonly referred to as
‘‘unconditional MFNs’’ or ‘‘cherrypicking MFNs,’’ require that a
programmer provide an MVPD the most
favorable term the programmer has
offered to any other distributor, even if
that other distributor agreed to
additional payment or other conditions
in exchange for receiving that term.7 As
a result of an unconditional MFN, the
programmer may be reluctant to license
the additional content to the other
distributor in the first place.
Although unconditional MFNs are
uncommon today, and the Defendants
have only a few such provisions in their
current contracts, the Department was
concerned that New Charter could
replace ADMs with unconditional
MFNs in an effort to circumvent the
proposed Final Judgment. For example,
New Charter might obtain an
unconditional MFN from a programmer
that would entitle New Charter to
receive at no additional cost any content
a programmer makes available to an
OVD, regardless of payments or other
conditions with which the OVD must
7 For example, a programmer may enter into an
agreement with Distributor A that provides
Distributor A with extra content (for instance,
additional video-on-demand rights) in exchange for
an extra payment. If the programmer has an
unconditional MFN with Distributor B, the
programmer may then be required to provide the
additional video-on-demand rights to Distributor B
without Distributor B having to make the extra
payment. By contrast, a more typical—and less
problematic—MFN would entitle Distributor B to
the additional content only if Distributor B agreed
to pay the same additional fee paid by Distributor
A.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
15:32 May 16, 2016
Jkt 238001
comply. In such case, by providing
programming to an OVD, the
programmer might face significant
economic disadvantages in the form of
losing the opportunity to monetize the
content through distribution by New
Charter. As a result, unconditional
MFNs could create significant
disincentives for programmers to license
content to OVDs. For these reasons,
Section IV.B.2 of the proposed Final
Judgment prohibits New Charter from
entering into or enforcing unconditional
MFNs against programmers for
distributing their content to OVDs.8
Section IV.C of the proposed Final
Judgment establishes three narrow
exceptions to the broad prohibitions in
Sections IV.A and IV.B. First, New
Charter may prohibit the programmer
from making content available on the
Internet for free for 30 days after its
initial airing, if New Charter has paid a
fee for the video programming. The
Department’s investigation revealed that
such limitations on free distribution are
ubiquitous in the industry, and the
Department has discovered no evidence
that such provisions are harmful to
competition.
Second, New Charter may enter into
an agreement in which the programmer
provides content exclusively to New
Charter, and to no other MVPD or OVD.
Although uncommon, a few
programmers wish to make some of
their content available to only one
distributor. This relationship then
incentivizes the distributor to
vigorously market the content, and thus
can be procompetitive in some
circumstances. The proposed Final
Judgment ensures that New Charter can
continue to compete with other
distributors to obtain these kinds of
exclusives. As long as the exclusivity
applies to all other video programming
distributors, and does not narrowly
prohibit distribution only to OVDs, the
Department has no basis to believe such
provisions will always or usually be
harmful.9
8 Specifically, Section IV.B.2.i provides that New
Charter may not require a programmer to provide
New Charter the same terms offered to an OVD
unless New Charter also accepts any conditions that
are integrally related, logically linked, or directly
tied to those terms. The language chosen for this
provision mirrors language that is common in
conditional MFN provisions throughout the
industry. Also consistent with other conditional
MFNs in the industry, Section IV.B.2.ii states that
Charter need not comply with related terms and
conditions if it is unable to do so for technological
or regulatory reasons.
9 The Department retains the authority to
challenge under Sections 1 or 2 of the Sherman Act
any exclusive agreement in the future that the
evidence demonstrates unreasonably restrains trade
or creates or enhances monopoly power. See
Proposed Final Judgment at § VII (No Limitation of
Government Rights).
PO 00000
Frm 00046
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
Third, New Charter may condition
carriage of programming on its cable
system on terms which require it to
receive as favorable material terms as
other MVPDs or OVDs, except to the
extent such terms would be inconsistent
with the purpose of the proposed Final
Judgment. That is, New Charter may
enter into the kinds of ordinary
conditional MFNs that are ubiquitous in
the industry, such as a provision which
entitles New Charter to the lowest
license fee paid by any other distributor.
This provision explicitly does not
override Section IV.B.2’s ban on the
application of unconditional MFNs to
OVD distribution. Importantly, New
Charter may not use MFNs as a back
door to obtain provisions which are
otherwise ‘‘inconsistent with the
purpose of Sections A and B.’’ For
instance, even if another distributor
obtains a provision which ‘‘create[s]
incentives to limit’’ a programmer’s
provision of programming to an OVD,
New Charter cannot use an MFN to add
that other distributor’s provision to New
Charter’s own contract.
2. The Proposed Final Judgment
Prohibits Defendants From
Discriminating Against, Retaliating
Against, or Punishing Video
Programmers
Section IV.D of the proposed Final
Judgment prohibits Defendants from
discriminating against, retaliating
against, or punishing any Video
Programmer for providing programming
to any OVD. This provision ensures that
even though Defendants are no longer
permitted to contractually prohibit or
deter video programmers from licensing
content to OVDs, the Defendants are not
able to instead deter such licensing
through threats or punishment. Section
IV.D also prohibits Defendants from
discriminating against, retaliating
against, or punishing any video
programmer for invoking any provisions
of the proposed Final Judgment or any
FCC rule or order, or for furnishing
information to the Department
concerning Defendants’ compliance
with the proposed Final Judgment.
Negotiations between video
programmers and MVPDs are often
contentious, high-stakes affairs, and it is
common for one or both sides to the
negotiation to threaten to walk away, or
even to temporarily terminate the
relationship (sometimes called a
‘‘blackout’’ or ‘‘going dark’’) in order to
secure a better deal. The proposed Final
Judgment is not concerned with such
negotiating tactics and therefore clarifies
that ‘‘[p]ursuing a more advantageous
deal with a Video Programmer does not
constitute discrimination, retaliation, or
E:\FR\FM\17MYN1.SGM
17MYN1
Federal Register / Vol. 81, No. 95 / Tuesday, May 17, 2016 / Notices
jstallworth on DSK7TPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
punishment.’’ Rather, Section IV.D is
designed to prevent situations where
New Charter intentionally decides to
forgo an agreement with a programmer
that would otherwise be economical for
New Charter in order to obtain the longterm benefits of deterring video
programmers from licensing content to
OVDs or cooperating with the
Department or the FCC.
3. Provision of Defendants’ FCC
Interconnection Reports
Although the Department’s Complaint
focuses on the likely competitive harm
resulting from New Charter’s imposition
of ADMs and other contractual
restrictions on video programmers, the
Department also investigated the
potential for the proposed merger to
increase the price New Charter will
charge Internet content companies,
including OVDs, for access to its
broadband subscribers. OVDs rely on
broadband connections provided by
other companies to reach their
customers, and the Defendants are also
major providers of Internet access
service. Therefore, the Department
examined whether the merger could
increase both the incentive and ability
of New Charter to use its control over
the interconnection to New Charter’s
broadband Internet service provider
network to try and disadvantage online
video competitors.
The FCC’s order approving the merger
imposes an obligation on New Charter
to make interconnection available on a
non-discriminatory, settlement-free
basis to any Internet content provider,
transit provider, or content delivery
network (‘‘CDN’’) who meets certain
basic criteria. Although this policy only
directly protects those sending large
volumes of traffic, even smaller sources
who do not qualify for direct
interconnection ought to find ample
bandwidth available at competitive
prices because large transit and CDN
providers will be guaranteed access, and
could resell that capacity. Thus, the
Department expects that the FCC’s order
will prevent any merger-related harm to
Internet content companies, including
OVDs. In light of the FCC’s remedy, the
Department did not target
interconnection in its Complaint and
elected not to pursue duplicative relief
with respect to interconnection in the
proposed Final Judgment. However, in
order to assist the Department in
monitoring future developments with
regard to interconnection and in taking
whatever action might be appropriate to
prevent anticompetitive conduct,
Section IV.E requires New Charter to
provide the Department with copies of
the regular reports that New Charter
VerDate Sep<11>2014
15:32 May 16, 2016
Jkt 238001
furnishes to the FCC pursuant to the
FCC’s order.
D. Term of the Proposed Final
Judgment
Section VIII of the proposed Final
Judgment provides that the Final
Judgment will expire seven years from
the date of entry. The Department
believes this time period is long enough
to ensure that New Charter cannot harm
OVD competitors at a crucial point in
their development while accounting for
the rapidly evolving nature of the video
distribution market. After five years,
Section VIII permits Charter to request
that the Department reevaluate whether
the Final Judgment remains necessary to
protect competition. If at such time the
Department concludes that the market
has evolved such that the protections of
the decree are no longer necessary, it
will recommend to the Court that the
Final Judgment be terminated.
IV. REMEDIES AVAILABLE TO
POTENTIAL PRIVATE LITIGANTS
Section 4 of the Clayton Act, 15
U.S.C. 15, provides that any person who
has been injured as a result of conduct
prohibited by the antitrust laws may
bring suit in federal court to recover
three times the damages the person has
suffered, as well as costs and reasonable
attorneys’ fees. Entry of the proposed
Final Judgment will neither impair nor
assist the bringing of any private
antitrust damage action. Under the
provisions of Section 5(a) of the Clayton
Act, 15 U.S.C. 16(a), the proposed Final
Judgment has no prima facie effect in
any subsequent private lawsuit that may
be brought against Defendants.
V. PROCEDURES AVAILABLE FOR
MODIFICATION OF THE PROPOSED
FINAL JUDGMENT
The United States and Defendants
have stipulated that the proposed Final
Judgment may be entered by the Court
after compliance with the provisions of
the APPA, provided that the United
States has not withdrawn its consent.
The APPA conditions entry upon the
Court’s determination that the proposed
Final Judgment is in the public interest.
The APPA provides a period of at
least 60 days preceding the effective
date of the proposed Final Judgment
within which any person may submit to
the United States written comments
regarding the proposed Final Judgment.
Any person who wishes to comment
should do so within 60 days of the date
of publication of this Competitive
Impact Statement in the Federal
Register, or the last date of publication
in a newspaper of the summary of this
Competitive Impact Statement,
PO 00000
Frm 00047
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
30561
whichever is later. All comments
received during this period will be
considered by the United States, which
remains free to withdraw its consent to
the proposed Final Judgment at any
time prior to the Court’s entry of
judgment. The comments and the
response of the United States will be
filed with the Court. In addition,
comments will be posted on the U.S.
Department of Justice, Antitrust
Division’s internet Web site and, under
certain circumstances, published in the
Federal Register. Written comments
should be submitted to:
Scott A. Scheele
Chief, Telecommunications and Media
Enforcement Section
Antitrust Division
United States Department of Justice
450 Fifth Street NW., Suite 7000
Washington, DC 20530
The proposed Final Judgment
provides that the Court retains
jurisdiction over this action, and the
parties may apply to the Court for any
order necessary or appropriate for the
modification, interpretation, or
enforcement of the Final Judgment.
VI. ALTERNATIVES TO THE
PROPOSED FINAL JUDGMENT
The United States considered, as an
alternative to the proposed Final
Judgment, seeking preliminary and
permanent injunctions against
Defendants’ transactions and proceeding
to a full trial on the merits. The United
States is satisfied, however, that the
relief in the proposed Final Judgment
will preserve competition for the
provision of video programming
distribution services in the United
States. Thus, the proposed Final
Judgment would protect competition as
effectively as would any remedy
available through litigation, but avoids
the time, expense, and uncertainty of a
full trial on the merits.
VII. STANDARD OF REVIEW UNDER
THE APPA FOR THE PROPOSED
FINAL JUDGMENT
The Clayton Act, as amended by the
APPA, requires that proposed consent
judgments in antitrust cases brought by
the United States be subject to a sixtyday comment period, after which the
court shall determine whether entry of
the proposed Final Judgment ‘‘is in the
public interest.’’ 15 U.S.C. 16(e)(1). In
making that determination, the court, in
accordance with the statute as amended
in 2004, is required to consider:
(A) the competitive impact of such
judgment, including termination of alleged
violations, provisions for enforcement and
modification, duration of relief sought,
E:\FR\FM\17MYN1.SGM
17MYN1
30562
Federal Register / Vol. 81, No. 95 / Tuesday, May 17, 2016 / Notices
anticipated effects of alternative remedies
actually considered, whether its terms are
ambiguous, and any other competitive
considerations bearing upon the adequacy of
such judgment that the court deems
necessary to a determination of whether the
consent judgment is in the public interest;
and
(B) the impact of entry of such judgment
upon competition in the relevant market or
markets, upon the public generally and
individuals alleging specific injury from the
violations set forth in the complaint
including consideration of the public benefit,
if any, to be derived from a determination of
the issues at trial.
jstallworth on DSK7TPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
15 U.S.C. 16(e)(1)(A) & (B). In
considering these statutory factors, the
Court’s inquiry is necessarily a limited
one as the government is entitled to
‘‘broad discretion to settle with the
defendant within the reaches of the
public interest.’’ United States v.
Microsoft Corp., 56 F.3d 1448, 1461
(D.C. Cir. 1995); see generally United
States v. SBC Commc’ns, Inc., 489 F.
Supp. 2d 1 (D.D.C. 2007) (assessing
public interest standard under the
Tunney Act); United States v, U.S.
Airways Group, Inc., 38 F. Supp. 3d 69,
75 (D.D.C. 2014) (explaining that the
‘‘court’s inquiry is limited’’ in Tunney
Act settlements); United States v. InBev
N.V./S.A., No. 08–1965 (JR), 2009–2
Trade Cas. (CCH) ¶ 76,736, 2009 U.S.
Dist. LEXIS 84787, at *3, (D.D.C. Aug.
11, 2009) (noting that the court’s review
of a consent judgment is limited and
only inquires ‘‘into whether the
government’s determination that the
proposed remedies will cure the
antitrust violations alleged in the
complaint was reasonable, and whether
the mechanism to enforce the final
judgment are clear and manageable.’’).10
As the United States Court of Appeals
for the District of Columbia Circuit has
held, under the APPA a court considers,
among other things, the relationship
between the remedy secured and the
specific allegations set forth in the
government’s complaint, whether the
decree is sufficiently clear, whether
enforcement mechanisms are sufficient,
and whether the decree may positively
harm third parties. See Microsoft, 56
F.3d at 1458–62. With respect to the
adequacy of the relief secured by the
decree, a court may not ‘‘engage in an
unrestricted evaluation of what relief
would best serve the public.’’ United
States v. BNS, Inc., 858 F.2d 456, 462
10 The 2004 amendments substituted ‘‘shall’’ for
‘‘may’’ in directing relevant factors for courts to
consider and amended the list of factors to focus on
competitive considerations and to address
potentially ambiguous judgment terms. Compare 15
U.S.C. 16(e) (2004), with 15 U.S.C. 16(e)(1) (2006);
see also SBC Commc’ns, 489 F. Supp. 2d at 11
(concluding that the 2004 amendments ‘‘effected
minimal changes’’ to Tunney Act review).
VerDate Sep<11>2014
15:32 May 16, 2016
Jkt 238001
(9th Cir. 1988) (quoting United States v.
Bechtel Corp., 648 F.2d 660, 666 (9th
Cir. 1981)); see also Microsoft, 56 F.3d
at 1460–62; United States v. Alcoa, Inc.,
152 F. Supp. 2d 37, 40 (D.D.C. 2001);
InBev, 2009 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 84787, at
*3. Courts have held that:
[t]he balancing of competing social and
political interests affected by a proposed
antitrust consent decree must be left, in the
first instance, to the discretion of the
Attorney General. The court’s role in
protecting the public interest is one of
insuring that the government has not
breached its duty to the public in consenting
to the decree. The court is required to
determine not whether a particular decree is
the one that will best serve society, but
whether the settlement is ‘‘within the reaches
of the public interest.’’ More elaborate
requirements might undermine the
effectiveness of antitrust enforcement by
consent decree.
Bechtel, 648 F.2d at 666 (emphasis
added) (citations omitted).11 In
determining whether a proposed
settlement is in the public interest, a
district court ‘‘must accord deference to
the government’s predictions about the
efficacy of its remedies, and may not
require that the remedies perfectly
match the alleged violations.’’ SBC
Commc’ns, 489 F. Supp. 2d at 17; see
also U.S. Airways, 38 F. Supp. 3d at 75
(noting that a court should not reject the
proposed remedies because it believes
others are preferable); Microsoft, 56 F.3d
at 1461 (noting the need for courts to be
‘‘deferential to the government’s
predictions as to the effect of the
proposed remedies’’); United States v.
Archer-Daniels-Midland Co., 272 F.
Supp. 2d 1, 6 (D.D.C. 2003) (noting that
the court should grant due respect to the
United States’ prediction as to the effect
of proposed remedies, its perception of
the market structure, and its views of
the nature of the case).
Courts have greater flexibility in
approving proposed consent decrees
than in crafting their own decrees
following a finding of liability in a
litigated matter. ‘‘[A] proposed decree
must be approved even if it falls short
of the remedy the court would impose
on its own, as long as it falls within the
range of acceptability or is ‘within the
reaches of public interest.’’’ United
States v. Am. Tel. & Tel. Co., 552 F.
11 Cf. BNS, 858 F.2d at 464 (holding that the
court’s ‘‘ultimate authority under the [APPA] is
limited to approving or disapproving the consent
decree’’); United States v. Gillette Co., 406 F. Supp.
713, 716 (D. Mass. 1975) (noting that, in this way,
the court is constrained to ‘‘look at the overall
picture not hypercritically, nor with a microscope,
but with an artist’s reducing glass’’). See generally
Microsoft, 56 F.3d at 1461 (discussing whether ‘‘the
remedies [obtained in the decree are] so
inconsonant with the allegations charged as to fall
outside of the ‘reaches of the public interest’’’).
PO 00000
Frm 00048
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
Supp. 131, 151 (D.D.C. 1982) (citations
omitted) (quoting United States v.
Gillette Co., 406 F. Supp. 713, 716 (D.
Mass. 1975)), aff’d sub nom. Maryland
v. United States, 460 U.S. 1001 (1983);
see also U.S. Airways, 38 F. Supp. 3d at
76 (noting that room must be made for
the government to grant concessions in
the negotiation process for settlements
(citing Microsoft, 56 F.3d at 1461);
United States v. Alcan Aluminum Ltd.,
605 F. Supp. 619, 622 (W.D. Ky. 1985)
(approving the consent decree even
though the court would have imposed a
greater remedy). To meet this standard,
the United States ‘‘need only provide a
factual basis for concluding that the
settlements are reasonably adequate
remedies for the alleged harms.’’ SBC
Commc’ns, 489 F. Supp. 2d at 17.
Moreover, the court’s role under the
APPA is limited to reviewing the
remedy in relationship to the violations
that the United States has alleged in its
Complaint, and does not authorize the
court to ‘‘construct [its] own
hypothetical case and then evaluate the
decree against that case.’’ Microsoft, 56
F.3d at 1459; see also U.S. Airways, 38
F. Supp. 3d at 75 (noting that the court
must simply determine whether there is
a factual foundation for the
government’s decisions such that its
conclusions regarding the proposed
settlements are reasonable); InBev, 2009
U.S. Dist. LEXIS 84787, at *20 (‘‘the
‘public interest’ is not to be measured by
comparing the violations alleged in the
complaint against those the court
believes could have, or even should
have, been alleged’’). Because the
‘‘court’s authority to review the decree
depends entirely on the government’s
exercising its prosecutorial discretion by
bringing a case in the first place,’’ it
follows that ‘‘the court is only
authorized to review the decree itself,’’
and not to ‘‘effectively redraft the
complaint’’ to inquire into other matters
that the United States did not pursue.
Microsoft, 56 F.3d at 1459–60. As this
Court confirmed in SBC
Communications, courts ‘‘cannot look
beyond the complaint in making the
public interest determination unless the
complaint is drafted so narrowly as to
make a mockery of judicial power.’’ SBC
Commc’ns, 489 F. Supp. 2d at 15.
In its 2004 amendments, Congress
made clear its intent to preserve the
practical benefits of utilizing consent
decrees in antitrust enforcement, adding
the unambiguous instruction that
‘‘[n]othing in this section shall be
construed to require the court to
conduct an evidentiary hearing or to
require the court to permit anyone to
intervene.’’ 15 U.S.C. 16(e)(2); see also
U.S. Airways, 38 F. Supp. 3d at 76
E:\FR\FM\17MYN1.SGM
17MYN1
Federal Register / Vol. 81, No. 95 / Tuesday, May 17, 2016 / Notices
(indicating that a court is not required
to hold an evidentiary hearing or to
permit intervenors as part of its review
under the Tunney Act). The language
wrote into the statute what Congress
intended when it enacted the Tunney
Act in 1974, as Senator Tunney
explained: ‘‘[t]he court is nowhere
compelled to go to trial or to engage in
extended proceedings which might have
the effect of vitiating the benefits of
prompt and less costly settlement
through the consent decree process.’’
119 Cong. Rec. 24,598 (1973) (statement
of Sen. Tunney). Rather, the procedure
for the public interest determination is
left to the discretion of the court, with
the recognition that the court’s ‘‘scope
of review remains sharply proscribed by
precedent and the nature of Tunney Act
proceedings.’’ SBC Commc’ns, 489 F.
Supp. 2d at 11.12 A court can make its
public interest determination based on
the competitive impact statement and
response to public comments alone.
U.S. Airways, 38 F. Supp. 3d at 76.
VIII. DETERMINATIVE DOCUMENTS
Appendix B to the FCC’s
Memorandum Opinion and Order, In re
Applications of Charter
Communications, Inc., Time Warner
Cable Inc., and Advance/Newhouse
Partnership for Consent to the Transfer
of Control of Licenses and
Authorizations, FCC MB Docket No. 15–
149 (adopted May 5, 2016; released May
10, 2016), was the only determinative
document or material within the
meaning of the APPA considered by the
Department in formulating the proposed
Final Judgment. This document is
available on the FCC’s Web site at
https://apps.fcc.gov/edocs_public/
attachmatch/FCC-16-59A1.pdf, and will
also be made available on the Antitrust
Division’s Web site at https://
www.justice.gov/atr/case/us-v-chartercommunications-inc-et-al.
jstallworth on DSK7TPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
Dated: May 10, 2016
Respectfully submitted,
12 See United States v. Enova Corp., 107 F. Supp.
2d 10, 17 (D.D.C. 2000) (noting that the ‘‘Tunney
Act expressly allows the court to make its public
interest determination on the basis of the
competitive impact statement and response to
comments alone’’); United States v. Mid-Am.
Dairymen, Inc., No. 73–CV–681–W–1, 1977–1 Trade
Cas. (CCH) ¶ 61,508, at 71,980, *22 (W.D.
Mo. 1977) (‘‘Absent a showing of corrupt failure
of the government to discharge its duty, the Court,
in making its public interest finding, should . . .
carefully consider the explanations of the
government in the competitive impact statement
and its responses to comments in order to
determine whether those explanations are
reasonable under the circumstances.’’); S. Rep. No.
93–298, at 6 (1973) (‘‘Where the public interest can
be meaningfully evaluated simply on the basis of
briefs and oral arguments, that is the approach that
should be utilized.’’).
VerDate Sep<11>2014
15:32 May 16, 2016
Jkt 238001
/s/ lllllllllllllllllll
Robert A. Lepore,
Telecommunications & Media, Enforcement
Section, Antitrust Division, U.S. Department
of Justice, 450 Fifth Street NW., Suite 7000,
Washington, DC 20530, Telephone: (202)
532–4928, Facsimile: (202) 514–6381, Email:
Robert.Lepore@usdoj.gov
United States District Court for the
District of Columbia
United States of America, Plaintiff, v.
Charter Communications, Inc., Time Warner
Cable Inc, Advance/Newhouse Partnership,
and Bright House Networks, LLC, Defendants.
Case No.: 1:16–cv–00759
Judge: Royce C. Lamberth
Filed: 04/25/2016
[PROPOSED] FINAL JUDGMENT
WHEREAS, Plaintiff, the United
States of America, filed its Complaint on
April 25, 2016 alleging that Defendants
propose to enter into transactions the
likely effect of which would be to lessen
competition substantially in the market
for the timely distribution of
professional, full-length video
programming to residential customers
(‘‘video programming distribution’’)
across the United States in violation of
Section 7 of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C.
18, and Plaintiff and Defendants, by
their respective attorneys, have
consented to the entry of this Final
Judgment without trial or adjudication
of any issue of fact or law, and without
this Final Judgment constituting any
evidence against or admission by any
party regarding any issue of fact or law;
AND WHEREAS, Defendants agree to
be bound by the provisions of this Final
Judgment pending its approval by the
Court;
AND WHEREAS, Plaintiff requires
Defendants to agree to undertake certain
actions and refrain from certain conduct
for the purpose of remedying the loss of
competition alleged in the Complaint;
AND WHEREAS, Defendants have
represented to the United States that the
actions and conduct restrictions can and
will be undertaken and that Defendants
will later raise no claim of hardship or
difficulty as grounds for asking the
Court to modify any of the provisions
contained below;
NOW THEREFORE, before any
testimony is taken, without trial or
adjudication of any issue of fact or law,
and upon consent of the parties, it is
ORDERED, ADJUDGED, AND
DECREED:
I. JURISDICTION
This Court has jurisdiction over the
subject matter of and each of the parties
to this action. The Complaint states a
claim upon which relief may be granted
against Defendants under Section 7 of
PO 00000
Frm 00049
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
30563
the Clayton Act, as amended, 15 U.S.C.
18.
II. DEFINITIONS
As used in this Final Judgment:
A. ‘‘Advance/Newhouse’’ means
defendant Advance/Newhouse
Partnership, a New York partnership
with headquarters in East Syracuse,
New York, its successors and assigns,
and its Subsidiaries, divisions, groups,
affiliates, partnerships and joint
ventures, and their directors, officers,
managers, agents, and employees, in
their capacity as directors, officers,
managers, agents, and employees of the
foregoing.
B. ‘‘Bright House’’ means defendant
Bright House Networks, LLC, a
Delaware limited liability company with
headquarters in East Syracuse, New
York, its successors and assigns, and its
Subsidiaries, divisions, groups,
affiliates, partnerships and joint
ventures, and their directors, officers,
managers, agents, and employees, in
their capacity as directors, officers,
managers, agents, and employees of the
foregoing.
C. ‘‘Charter’’ means defendant Charter
Communications, Inc., a Delaware
corporation with headquarters in
Stamford, Connecticut, its successors
and assigns (including, without
limitation, CCH I, LLC), and its
Subsidiaries, divisions, groups,
affiliates, partnerships and joint
ventures, and their directors, officers,
managers, agents, and employees, in
their capacity as directors, officers,
managers, agents, and employees of the
foregoing.
D. ‘‘Defendants’’ means Charter, TWC,
Bright House, and Advance/Newhouse,
acting individually or collectively.
Notwithstanding the foregoing,
Advance/Newhouse is not a
‘‘Defendant’’ for purposes of Section IV.
E. ‘‘Department of Justice’’ means the
United States Department of Justice
Antitrust Division.
F. ‘‘MVPD’’ means a multichannel
video programming distributor as that
term is defined on the date of entry of
this Final Judgment in 47 CFR
76.1200(b), in its capacity as an MVPD.
G. ‘‘OVD’’ means any service that (1)
distributes Video Programming in the
United States by means of the Internet;
(2) is not a component of an MVPD
subscription; and (3) is not solely
available to customers of an Internet
access service owned or operated by the
Person providing the service or an
affiliate of the Person providing the
service. For avoidance of doubt, this
definition (1) includes a service offered
by a Video Programmer for the
distribution of its own Video
E:\FR\FM\17MYN1.SGM
17MYN1
jstallworth on DSK7TPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
30564
Federal Register / Vol. 81, No. 95 / Tuesday, May 17, 2016 / Notices
Programming by means of the Internet
to Persons other than subscribers of an
MVPD service; (2) includes a service
offered by an MVPD that offers Video
Programming by means of the Internet
outside its MVPD service territory as a
service separate and independent of an
MVPD subscription; and (3) excludes an
MVPD that offers Video Programming
by means of the Internet to homes inside
its MVPD service territory as a
component of an MVPD subscription.
H. ‘‘Person’’ means any natural
person, corporation, company,
partnership, joint venture, firm,
association, proprietorship, agency,
board, authority, commission, office, or
other business or legal entity, whether
private or governmental.
I. ‘‘Subsidiary’’ refers to any Person in
which there is partial (25 percent or
more) or total ownership or control
between the specified Person and any
other Person. Notwithstanding the
foregoing, Subsidiary shall not include
any Person in which a Defendant does
not have majority ownership or de facto
control if that Person does not provide
MVPD service.
J. ‘‘TWC’’ means defendant Time
Warner Cable Inc, a New York
corporation with headquarters in New
York, New York, its successors and
assigns, and its Subsidiaries, divisions,
groups, affiliates, partnerships and joint
ventures, and their directors, officers,
managers, agents, and employees, in
their capacity as directors, officers,
managers, agents, and employees of the
foregoing.
K. ‘‘Video Programmer’’ means any
Person that provides Video
Programming for distribution through
MVPDs, in its capacity as a Video
Programmer.
L. ‘‘Video Programming’’ means
programming provided by, or generally
considered comparable to programming
provided by, a television broadcast
station or cable network, regardless of
the medium or method used for
distribution, and, without expanding
the foregoing, includes programming
prescheduled by the programming
provider (also known as scheduled
programming or a linear feed);
programming offered to viewers on an
on-demand, point-to-point basis (also
known as video on demand); pay per
view or transactional video on demand;
short programming segments related to
other full-length programming (also
known as clips); programming that
includes multiple video sources (also
known as feeds, including camera
angles); programming that includes
video in different qualities or formats
(including high-definition and 3D); and
VerDate Sep<11>2014
15:32 May 16, 2016
Jkt 238001
films for which a year or more has
elapsed since their theatrical release.
III. APPLICABILITY
This Final Judgment applies to
Defendants and all other Persons in
active concert or participation with any
of them who receive actual notice of this
Final Judgment by personal service or
otherwise.
IV. PROHIBITED CONDUCT AND
REPORTING
A. Defendants shall not enter into or
enforce any agreement with a Video
Programmer under which Defendants
forbid, limit, or create incentives to
limit the Video Programmer’s provision
of its Video Programming to one or more
OVDs.
B. Agreements that ‘‘create incentives
to limit’’ a Video Programmer’s
provision of its Video Programming to
one or more OVDs within the meaning
of Section IV.A shall include, but are
not limited to, the following:
1. agreements that provide for any
pecuniary or non-pecuniary penalty on
the Video Programmer for the provision
of its Video Programming to an OVD,
such as rate reductions, re-tiering or repositioning penalties, termination rights
for Defendants, or loss or waiver of any
rights or benefits otherwise available to
the Video Programmer; or
2. agreements that entitle Defendants
to receive any benefits such as favorable
rates, contract terms, or content rights
offered or granted to an OVD by a Video
Programmer without requiring
Defendants to also accept any
obligations, limitations, or conditions:
i. that are integrally related, logically
linked, or directly tied to the offering or
grant of such rights or benefits, and
ii. with which Defendants can
reasonably comply technologically and
legally. For avoidance of doubt,
Defendants will be deemed able to
‘‘reasonably comply technologically’’ if
they are able to implement an
obligation, limitation, or condition in a
technologically equivalent manner.
C. Notwithstanding the foregoing,
nothing in this Final Judgment shall
prohibit Defendants from:
1. entering into and enforcing an
agreement under which Defendants
discourage or prohibit a Video
Programmer from making Video
Programming for which Defendants pay
available to consumers for free over the
Internet within the first 30 days after
Defendants first distribute the Video
Programming to consumers;
2. entering into and enforcing an
agreement under which the Video
Programmer provides Video
PO 00000
Frm 00050
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
Programming exclusively to Defendants,
and to no other MVPD or OVD; or
3. entering into and enforcing an
agreement which requires that
Defendants receive as favorable material
terms as other MVPDs or OVDs, except
to the extent application of other
MVPDs’ or OVDs’ terms would be
inconsistent with the purpose of
Sections A and B of this Section IV.
D. Defendants shall not discriminate
against, retaliate against, or punish any
Video Programmer (i) for providing
Video Programming to any MVPD or
OVD, (ii) for invoking any provisions of
this Final Judgment, (iii) for invoking
the provisions of any rules or orders
concerning Video Programming adopted
by the Federal Communications
Commission, or (iv) for furnishing
information to the United States
concerning Defendants’ compliance or
noncompliance with this Final
Judgment. Pursuing a more
advantageous deal with a Video
Programmer does not constitute
discrimination, retaliation, or
punishment.
E. Defendants shall submit to the
Department of Justice all reports and
data relating to interconnection with the
Defendants’ broadband Internet access
network that are required to be
submitted to the Federal
Communications Commission (‘‘the
Commission’’) pursuant to any rule or
order of the Commission, at the same
time such reports or data are required to
be submitted to the Commission.
V. COMPLIANCE INSPECTION
A. For purposes of determining or
securing compliance with this Final
Judgment, or of determining whether
the Final Judgment should be modified
or vacated, and subject to any legally
recognized privilege, from time to time
duly authorized representatives of the
Department of Justice, including
consultants and other persons retained
by the Department of Justice, shall,
upon written request of an authorized
representative of the Assistant Attorney
General in charge of the Antitrust
Division, and on reasonable notice to
Defendants, be permitted:
1. access during the Defendants’ office
hours to inspect and copy, or at the
option of the United States, to require
Defendants to provide to the United
States hard copy or electronic copies of,
all books, ledgers, accounts, records,
data, and documents in the possession,
custody, or control of Defendants,
relating to any matters contained in this
Final Judgment; and
2. to interview, either informally or on
the record, the Defendants’ officers,
employees, or agents, who may have
E:\FR\FM\17MYN1.SGM
17MYN1
Federal Register / Vol. 81, No. 95 / Tuesday, May 17, 2016 / Notices
their individual counsel present,
regarding such matters. The interviews
shall be subject to the reasonable
convenience of the interviewee and
without restraint or interference by
Defendants.
B. Upon the written request of an
authorized representative of the
Assistant Attorney General in charge of
the Antitrust Division, Defendants shall
submit written reports or respond to
written interrogatories, under oath if
requested, relating to any of the matters
contained in this Final Judgment as may
be requested.
C. No information or documents
obtained by the means provided in this
section shall be divulged by the United
States to any person other than an
authorized representative of the
executive branch of the United States or
the Federal Communications
Commission, except in the course of
legal proceedings to which the United
States is a party (including grand jury
proceedings), or for the purpose of
securing compliance with this Final
Judgment, or as otherwise required by
law.
D. If at the time information or
documents are furnished by a Defendant
to the United States, the Defendant
represents and identifies in writing the
material in any such information or
documents to which a claim of
protection may be asserted under Rule
26(c)(1)(G) of the Federal Rules of Civil
Procedure, and the Defendant marks
each pertinent page of such material,
‘‘Subject to claim of protection under
Rule 26(c)(1)(G) of the Federal Rules of
Civil Procedure,’’ then the United States
shall give the Defendant ten calendar
days notice prior to divulging such
material in any civil or administrative
proceeding (other than a grand jury
proceeding).
VI. RETENTION OF JURISDICTION
jstallworth on DSK7TPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
This Court retains jurisdiction to
enable any party to apply to this Court
at any time for further orders and
directions as may be necessary or
appropriate to carry out or construe this
Final Judgment, to modify any of its
provisions, to enforce compliance, and
to punish violations of its provisions.
VII. NO LIMITATION ON
GOVERNMENT RIGHTS
Nothing in this Final Judgment shall
limit the right of the United States to
investigate and bring actions to prevent
or restrain violations of the antitrust
laws concerning any past, present, or
future conduct, policy, or practice of the
Defendants.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
15:32 May 16, 2016
Jkt 238001
VIII. EXPIRATION OF FINAL
JUDGMENT
30565
9, with a one hour break for lunch each
day. The purpose of the open meeting
is for Advisory Council members to hear
This Final Judgment shall expire
testimony from invited witnesses and to
seven years from the date of its entry.
receive an update from the Employee
Notwithstanding the foregoing, the
Benefits Security Administration
Defendants may request after five years
(EBSA). The EBSA update is scheduled
that the Department of Justice examine
for the morning of June 9, subject to
competitive conditions and determine
change.
whether the Final Judgment continues
to be necessary to protect competition.
The Advisory Council will study the
If after examination of competitive
following topics: (1) Cybersecurity
conditions the Department of Justice in
Considerations for Benefit Plans, on
its sole discretion concludes that the
June 7 and (2) Participant Plan Transfers
Final Judgment should be terminated, it and Account Consolidation for the
will recommend to the Court that the
Advancement of Lifetime Plan
Final Judgment be terminated.
Participation, on June 8. The schedule is
IX. PUBLIC INTEREST
subject to change. The Council will
DETERMINATION
discuss both topics on June 9.
Descriptions of these topics are
Entry of this Final Judgment is in the
available on the Advisory Council page
public interest. The parties have
of the EBSA Web site, at www.dol.gov/
complied with the requirements of the
ebsa/aboutebsa/
Antitrust Procedures and Penalties Act,
erisaadvisorycouncil.html.
15 U.S.C. 16, including making copies
available to the public of this Final
Organizations or members of the
Judgment, the Competitive Impact
public wishing to submit a written
Statement, and any comments thereon
statement may do so by submitting 35
and the United States’ responses to
copies on or before May 31, 2016 to
comments. Based upon the record
Larry Good, Executive Secretary, ERISA
before the Court, which includes the
Advisory Council, U.S. Department of
Competitive Impact Statement and any
Labor, Suite N–5623, 200 Constitution
comments and response to comments
Avenue NW., Washington, DC 20210.
filed with the Court, entry of this Final
Statements also may be submitted as
Judgment is in the public interest.
email attachments in word processing or
Date: llllllllllllllllll pdf format transmitted to good.larry@
Court approval subject to procedures set forth dol.gov. It is requested that statements
in the Antitrust Procedures and Penalties
not be included in the body of the
Act, 15 U.S.C. 16
email. Statements deemed relevant by
lllllllllllllllllllll
the Advisory Council and received on or
United States District Judge
before May 31 will be included in the
[FR Doc. 2016–11562 Filed 5–16–16; 8:45 am]
record of the meeting and made
BILLING CODE 4410–11–P
available through the EBSA Public
Disclosure Room, along with witness
statements. Do not include any
DEPARTMENT OF LABOR
personally identifiable information
(such as name, address, or other contact
Employee Benefits Security
information) or confidential business
Administration
information that you do not want
publicly disclosed. Written statements
181st Meeting of the Advisory Council
submitted by invited witnesses will be
on Employee Welfare and Pension
posted on the Advisory Council page of
Benefit Plans Notice of Meeting
the EBSA Web site, without change, and
Pursuant to the authority contained in can be retrieved by most Internet search
section 512 of the Employee Retirement engines.
Income Security Act of 1974 (ERISA), 29
Individuals or representatives of
U.S.C. 1142, the 181st meeting of the
Advisory Council on Employee Welfare organizations wishing to address the
Advisory Council should forward their
and Pension Benefit Plans (also known
requests to the Executive Secretary or
as the ERISA Advisory Council) will be
telephone (202) 693–8668. Oral
held on June 7–9, 2016.
The three-day meeting will take place presentations will be limited to 10
minutes, time permitting, but an
at the U.S. Department of Labor, 200
Constitution Avenue NW., Washington, extended statement may be submitted
for the record. Individuals with
DC 20210 in C5320 Room 6. The
disabilities who need special
meeting will run from 9:00 a.m. to
accommodations should contact the
approximately 5:30 p.m. on June 7–8
Executive Secretary by May 31.
and from 8:30 a.m. to 3:00 p.m. on June
PO 00000
Frm 00051
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
E:\FR\FM\17MYN1.SGM
17MYN1
Agencies
[Federal Register Volume 81, Number 95 (Tuesday, May 17, 2016)]
[Notices]
[Pages 30550-30565]
From the Federal Register Online via the Government Publishing Office [www.gpo.gov]
[FR Doc No: 2016-11562]
=======================================================================
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE
Antitrust Division
United States v. Charter Communications, Inc., et al.; Proposed
Final Judgment and Competitive Impact Statement
Notice is hereby given pursuant to the Antitrust Procedures and
Penalties Act, 15 U.S.C. 16(b)-(h), that a proposed Final Judgment,
Stipulation, and Competitive Impact Statement have been filed with the
United States District Court for the District of Columbia in United
States of America v. Charter Communications, Inc., et al., Civil Action
No. 16-cv-00759. On April 25, 2016, the United States filed a Complaint
alleging that Charter Communications, Inc.'s proposed acquisitions of
Time Warner Cable Inc. and Bright House Networks, LLC would violate
Section 7 of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. 18. The proposed Final
Judgment, filed at the same time as the Complaint, forbids the merged
company from engaging in certain conduct that could make it more
difficult for competing online video distributors (OVDs) to obtain
programming content.
Copies of the Complaint, proposed Final Judgment, and Competitive
Impact Statement are available for inspection on the Antitrust
Division's Web site at https://www.justice.gov/atr and at the Office of
the Clerk of the United States District Court for the District of
Columbia. Copies of these materials may be obtained from the Antitrust
Division upon request and payment of the copying fee set by Department
of Justice regulations.
Public comment is invited within 60 days of the date of this
notice. Such comments, including the name of the submitter, and
responses thereto, will be posted on the Antitrust Division's Web site,
filed with the Court, and, under certain circumstances, published in
the Federal Register. Comments should be directed to Scott A. Scheele,
Chief, Telecommunications and Media Enforcement Section, Antitrust
Division, Department of Justice, 450 Fifth Street NW., Suite 7000,
Washington, DC 20530 (telephone: 202-616-5924).
Patricia A. Brink,
Director of Civil Enforcement.
UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA
United States of America, Department of Justice, Antitrust
Division, 450 5th Street N.W., Suite 7000, Washington, DC, 20530,
Plaintiff, v., Charter Communications, Inc., 400 Atlantic Street,
Stamford, CT 06901, Time Warner Cable Inc., 60 Columbus Circle, New
York, NY 10023, Advance/Newhouse Partnership, 5823 Widewaters
Parkway, East Syracuse, NY 13057, and, Bright House Networks, LLC,
5823 Widewaters Parkway, East Syracuse, NY 13057, Defendants.
Case No.: 1:16-cv-00759
Judge: Royce C. Lamberth
Filed: 04/25/2016
[[Page 30551]]
COMPLAINT
The United States of America, acting under the direction of the
Attorney General of the United States, brings this civil antitrust
action to enjoin the proposed combination of Charter Communications,
Inc. (``Charter''), Time Warner Cable Inc. (``TWC''), and Advance/
Newhouse Partnership's (``Advance/Newhouse'') subsidiary, Bright House
Networks, LLC (``BHN'') (collectively referred to herein as ``New
Charter''), which would create the second-largest cable company and the
third-largest multi-channel video distributor in the United States.
I. INTRODUCTION
1. Online video programming distributors (``OVDs'') are beginning
to revolutionize the way Americans receive and experience video
content. With access to an adequate Internet connection, consumers can
now choose among a number of OVDs to access collections of movies and
television shows, including original content, at any time and on a
device of their choosing. The early OVDs, such as Netflix, Hulu, and
Amazon, focused on offering on-demand video to their customers and have
developed video services that have already proven popular. Several
newer OVDs, including DISH Network's Sling TV and Sony's Playstation
Vue, have introduced services that offer live television channels in
addition to on-demand content. And several television networks,
including CBS, HBO, and Showtime, have launched OVD services to
distribute their own programming over the Internet directly to
subscribers. Continued growth of OVDs promises to deliver more
competitive choices and a greater ability for consumers to customize
their consumption of video content to their individual viewing
preferences and budgets.
2. The emergence of OVDs threatens to upend the competitive
landscape. For years, incumbent cable companies such as Comcast, TWC,
and Charter have served the majority of American video households.
Although these companies now face competition from the two direct
broadcast satellite (``DBS'') providers, DirecTV and DISH Network, and,
in some areas, from telephone companies (``telcos'') like AT&T and
Verizon that also offer video services, all of these distributors--
collectively referred to as multichannel video programming distributors
(``MVPDs'')--offer fairly similar products and pricing. Most notably,
all of these MVPDs sell content to consumers primarily through large
and costly video bundles that include hundreds of channels of
programming that many customers neither desire nor watch.
3. In order for an OVD to successfully compete with the traditional
MVPDs, it needs both the ability to reach consumers over the Internet
and the ability to obtain programming from content providers that
consumers will want to watch. Importantly, incumbent cable companies
often can exert significant influence over one or both of these
essential ingredients to an OVD's success, because they provide
broadband connectivity that OVDs need to reach consumers and are also a
critical distribution channel for the same video programmers that
supply OVDs with video content. To the extent a transaction, such as
the one at issue here, enhances an MVPD's ability or incentive to
restrain OVDs' access to either of these critical inputs, and thus to
prevent OVDs from becoming a meaningful new competitive option,
consumers lose.
4. MVPDs have responded to the emergence of OVDs in various ways.
Many MVPDs have sought to keep their customers from migrating some or
all of their viewing to OVDs by taking steps to make their services
more attractive to consumers, for example, by allowing their
subscribers to receive programming over the Internet through Web sites
or apps and providing expanded video-on-demand offerings. But some
MVPDs have sought to restrain nascent OVD competition directly by
exercising their leverage over video programmers to restrict the
programmers' ability to license content to OVDs. To this end, some
MVPDs have sought so-called Alternative Distribution Means (``ADM'')
clauses in their programming contracts that prohibit programmers from
distributing content online, or have placed significant restrictions on
online distribution. No MVPD has sought and obtained these restrictive
ADMs as frequently, or as successfully, as TWC.
5. The combination of TWC with Charter and BHN will result in a
larger MVPD with a greater ability and incentive to secure restrictions
on programmers that limit or foreclose OVD access to important content.
The Defendants, along with other MVPDs and OVDs, compete with one
another as buyers of video content and serve as alternative
distribution channels for national video programmers to build
viewership scale. Since New Charter would have nearly 60 percent more
subscribers than TWC standing alone, the merger will make New Charter a
more vital distribution channel for these video programmers than each
of the Defendants individually. Hence, as a result of the merger, New
Charter will have greater bargaining leverage to insist that video
programmers limit their distribution to OVDs.
6. In addition, with its much larger subscriber base, New Charter
would gain significant additional benefits from impeding OVD
competition. Today, Charter, TWC, and BHN each only act to protect its
own MVPD profits. After the merger, however, New Charter would act to
protect the much larger combined video revenues of all three
Defendants. That is, while prior to the merger TWC has an incentive to
obtain restrictive contract clauses to protect its $10.4 billion in
video revenues, New Charter would have a much larger incentive to
protect the Defendants' over $16 billion in aggregated video revenues.
7. With more to gain from imposing ADMs and other contractual
restrictions and with greater bargaining leverage with programmers to
insist on such provisions, New Charter will be well-positioned to
restrain continued OVD growth by limiting or foreclosing OVD access to
the video content that is vital to their competitiveness. Accordingly,
the proposed combination of Charter, TWC, and BHN is likely to
substantially lessen competition in the provision of video programming
distribution in violation of Section 7 of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C.
18, and should be enjoined.
II. JURISDICTION AND VENUE
8. The United States brings this action under Section 15 of the
Clayton Act, as amended, 15 U.S.C. 25, to prevent and restrain Charter,
TWC, and BHN from violating Section 7 of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. 18.
9. Defendants Charter, TWC, and BHN all provide video distribution
services to programmers in the flow of interstate commerce,
distributing video programming to millions of consumers in numerous
states within the United States. Accordingly, Defendants' activities
substantially affect interstate commerce. The Court has subject matter
jurisdiction over this action and these Defendants pursuant to Section
15 of the Clayton Act, as amended, 15 U.S.C. 25, and 28 U.S.C. 1331,
1337(a), and 1345.
10. Defendants have consented to personal jurisdiction and venue in
the District of Columbia for the purposes of this action.
III. THE PARTIES AND THE PROPOSED TRANSACTION
11. Defendant Charter is a Delaware corporation with headquarters
in
[[Page 30552]]
Stamford, Connecticut. With over 4.2 million video subscribers across
28 states, Charter is the third-largest cable company in the United
States (behind Comcast and TWC) and the sixth-largest MVPD in the
nation. In 2014, Charter reported total revenues of around $9.1
billion. Nearly 49% of those revenues, around $4.4 billion, were
derived from Charter's video business.
12. Defendant TWC is a New York corporation with headquarters in
New York, New York. With over 10.8 million video subscribers across 30
states, TWC is the second-largest cable company in the United States
(behind only Comcast), and the fourth-largest MVPD in the country. In
2014, TWC reported total revenues of approximately $22.8 billion.
Around 45% of those revenues, or about $10.4 billion, were derived from
TWC's video business.
13. Defendant Advance/Newhouse is a New York partnership with
headquarters in East Syracuse, New York, and the sole owner of
Defendant BHN, a Delaware limited liability company headquartered in
East Syracuse, New York. BHN is the sixth-largest cable company in the
United States and the ninth-largest MVPD. BHN owns cable systems
serving around 2 million video customers across six states. In 2014,
BHN generated total revenues of around $3.7 billion, approximately $1.5
billion of which were derived from its video business.
14. On May 23, 2015, Charter, TWC, and Advance/Newhouse entered
into a series of agreements that would combine Charter, TWC, and BHN
into a single company, New Charter. Pursuant to these agreements, (1)
Charter and TWC would merge in a transaction valued at over $78
billion; and (2) Charter would acquire BHN from Advance/Newhouse in a
transaction valued at $10.4 billion. The combined entity would have
nearly 17.4 million video subscribers across 41 states, making it the
second-largest cable company and third-largest MVPD, accounting for
nearly 18% of all MVPD subscribers in the United States.
IV. THE VIDEO PROGRAMMING DISTRIBUTION INDUSTRY
15. There are two distinct levels to the video programming
distribution industry. At the ``upstream'' level, video programmers
license their content to video programming distributors--both OVDs and
traditional MVPDs including Charter, TWC, and BHN. At the
``downstream'' level, the video programming distributors then sell
subscriptions to various packages of that content and deliver the
content to residential customers.
[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN17MY16.332
16. Video programmers produce themselves, or acquire from other
copyright holders, a collection of professional, full-length programs
and movies. These video programmers then typically aggregate this
content into branded networks (e.g., NBC, ESPN, or The History Channel)
to create a 24-hour-per-day television service that is attractive to
consumers. Many of the largest video programmers control the rights to
multiple networks. Except for networks of purely local or regional
interest, the video programmers will contract with video programming
distributors across the country to distribute the content to consumers.
17. In order to acquire the rights to distribute each network,
video programming distributors pay the video programmer a license fee.
Generally, MVPDs and OVDs pay the video programmer a monthly per-
subscriber fee. These license fees are an important revenue stream for
video programmers. Most of the remainder of their revenues comes from
fees for advertisements placed on their networks.
18. Video programmers rely on video programming distributors to
reach consumers. Unless a video programmer obtains carriage in the
packages of video programming distributors that reach a sufficient
number of consumers, the programmers will be unable to earn enough
revenue in licensing or to attract enough advertising revenue to
generate a return on their investments in content. For this reason,
video programmers prefer to have as many video programming distributors
as possible carry their networks, and particularly seek out the largest
MVPDs that reach the most customers. If the programmer is unable to
agree on acceptable terms with a particular distributor, the
programmer's content will not be available to that distributor's
customers. This potential consequence gives the largest MVPDs
significant bargaining leverage in their negotiations with programmers.
V. RELEVANT MARKET
19. The timely distribution of professional, full-length video
programming to residential customers (``video programming
distribution'') constitutes a relevant product market and line of
commerce under Section 7 of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. 18. Both
[[Page 30553]]
MVPDs and OVDs are participants in this market.
20. Video programming distribution is characterized by the
aggregation and delivery of professionally produced content. This
content includes scripted and unscripted television shows, live
programming, sports, news, and movies licensed from a mixture of
broadcast and cable networks, as well as from movie studios. Video
programming can be viewed immediately by consumers, whether on demand
or as scheduled.
21. Consumers purchase video programming distribution services from
among those distributors that can offer such services directly to their
home. The DBS operators, DirecTV and DISH, can reach almost any
customer in the continental United States who has an unobstructed line
of sight to their satellites. OVDs are available to any consumer with
Internet service sufficient to deliver video of an acceptable quality.
In contrast, wireline-based distributors such as cable companies and
telcos generally must obtain a franchise from local, municipal, or
state authorities in order to construct and operate a wireline network
in a specific area, and then build lines to homes in that area. A
consumer cannot purchase video programming distribution services from a
wireline distributor operating outside its franchise area because the
distributor does not have the facilities to reach the consumer's home.
Thus, although the set of video programming distributors able to offer
service to individual consumers' residences is generally the same
within each local community, the set can differ from one local
community to another.
22. Each local community whose residents face the same competitive
choices in video programming distribution comprises a local geographic
market and section of the country under Section 7 of the Clayton Act,
15 U.S.C. 18. A hypothetical monopolist of video programming
distribution in any of these geographic areas could profitably raise
prices by a small but significant, non-transitory amount.
23. The specific geographic markets relevant to this action are the
numerous local markets throughout the United States shown in the map
below where either Charter, TWC, or BHN is the incumbent cable
operator.
[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN17MY16.333
In order to protect its profits in these geographic markets, which
cover around 48 million U.S. television households across 41 states,
New Charter will have an incentive to prevent rival OVDs from
obtaining, or to raise the costs of those rivals obtaining, programming
for their services. Because these OVD competitors also serve homes
outside New Charter's service areas, however, other local markets may
be affected, with the anticompetitive effects of the transaction likely
extending to the whole nation.
VI. MARKET CONCENTRATION
24. The incumbent cable companies typically have the highest share
of subscribers within their respective service areas, often above 50
percent. The DBS providers, DirecTV and DISH, account for approximately
one-third of the video programming distribution subscribers nationwide,
although their shares vary by local market. The telcos, AT&T and
Verizon, account for over 10 percent of video programming distribution
nationwide and have successfully achieved penetration of up to 40
percent in some areas, but their video services remain limited to
certain local markets and are unavailable to most American homes. In a
handful of areas, other providers called ``overbuilders'' have
constructed an additional wireline network to residential consumers,
offering another competitive option for video and broadband service.
But these overbuilders, including companies like RCN and Google Fiber,
are available in very few communities, serving less than two percent of
U.S. television households nationwide.
25. Although OVDs have acquired a significant number of customers
over the last several years, they account for only five percent of
total video programming distribution revenues. Nevertheless,
established distributors such as Charter, TWC, and BHN view OVDs as a
growing competitive threat and have taken steps to respond to OVD
entry.
[[Page 30554]]
VII. ANTICOMPETITIVE EFFECTS
26. Charter, TWC, and BHN compete with DBS, overbuilder, and telco
providers by upgrading their existing services, offering promotions and
other price discounts, and introducing new product offerings. Consumers
benefit from this competition by receiving better quality services,
lower prices, and more programming choices. Competition between the
incumbent cable companies and these alternative video providers has
also fostered innovation, including the development of digital
transmission, HD, and 4K programming, and the introduction of DVRs,
video-on-demand, and ways to view content on other devices or away from
home.
27. The continued development and expansion of OVDs could unlock
additional competitive benefits. Today, many consumers purchase OVD
services as a supplement to a traditional MVPD subscription. But in
light of expanding OVD options, some consumers are switching from
larger, more expensive MVPD bundles to slimmer and cheaper bundles. A
small number of consumers are even ``cutting the cord''--cancelling
their MVPD subscription altogether and relying solely on one or more
OVDs to receive content. And many younger consumers are emerging as
``cord nevers'' that do not seek out an MVPD subscription in the first
place. Large cable companies such as Charter and TWC, which rely on
their video businesses to deliver significant profit margins, have
observed these developments with growing concern. In numerous internal
documents, Defendants show a keen awareness of the competitive threat
that OVDs pose. In fact, a TWC board presentation from February 2014
illustrated the threat posed by such emerging online competitors as a
meteor speeding toward earth:
[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN17MY16.334
28. Because of the threat OVDs pose to their video business, some
MVPDs have an incentive to engage in tactics that would diminish OVDs'
ability to compete. TWC, in particular, has recognized that it can use
its contracts with video programmers to try and foreclose OVD
competitors from access to valuable content. TWC has been the most
aggressive MVPD in the industry in seeking and obtaining restrictive
contract provisions in its agreements with programmers that limit the
programmer's ability to license programming to OVDs. Specifically, TWC
has used the leverage that comes from its status as an important
distribution channel for many video programmers to secure ADM
provisions that either prevent the programmer from distributing its
content online, or place certain restrictions on such online
distribution. For example, some of TWC's ADMs prohibit any online
distribution for a certain period of time; others prevent the
programmers from distributing their content through OVDs that do not
meet specific criteria that can be difficult for OVDs to satisfy (e.g.,
requiring the OVD to include a minimum number of programming networks
in its service).
29. Although they offer service to residential customers in
different local areas, each of the Defendants serves as an alternative
distribution channel for nationwide video programmers to deliver their
content to consumers and to build national viewership scale. Video
programmers rely on traditional MVPDs to provide licensing fees and to
build a large viewership base that is attractive to advertisers. Post-
merger, New Charter will become one of the largest MVPDs in the country
and will serve as a critical distributor for video programmers,
offering access to over 17 million customers spread across 41 states.
As a result, New Charter will have more leverage to demand that video
programmers agree to forego or limit the licensing of programming to
OVDs.
30. In addition, New Charter will have greater incentive to engage
in conduct designed to make OVDs less competitive because the merged
firm will be significantly larger than any of the Defendants
individually. Because New Charter will have far more subscribers, it
will also stand to lose more profits as OVDs continue to take business
from traditional video distributors. Today,
[[Page 30555]]
any conduct that Charter engages in to harm OVDs would only benefit
Charter within its own service territory. After the merger, New Charter
will internalize the combined benefits to Charter, TWC, and BHN of
harming OVDs and therefore will have a greater incentive to do so, and
will be willing to offer more consideration to video programmers to
obtain licensing restrictions.
31. Restrictions imposed on video programmers by New Charter will
likely make it more difficult for OVDs to obtain important content from
programmers in the future. In order to comply with New Charter's
restrictions, video programmers may have to effectively cease providing
certain programming to an OVD altogether, or may be obligated to impose
burdensome conditions on an OVD (such as the requirement to include a
minimum number of programming networks in the service). Such actions
could negatively affect OVDs' business models and undermine their
ability to provide robust video offerings that compete with the
offerings of traditional MVPDs. By limiting OVDs' access to content
that is important to their customers, the competitiveness of OVDs will
likely be diminished and consumers will likely receive lower-quality
services and fewer choices.
VIII. ENTRY
32. Entry or expansion of traditional video programming
distributors will not be timely, likely, or sufficient to reverse the
competitive harm that would likely result from the proposed merger of
Charter, TWC, and BHN. Entry and expansion in the traditional video
programming distribution business is difficult and time-consuming
because it requires an enormous upfront investment to create
distribution infrastructure such as building out wireline facilities or
launching satellites. Entry or expansion into a new geographic area
also typically requires approval from one or more regulatory bodies.
33. OVDs are less likely to enter or expand to develop into
significant competitors if denied access to popular content as a result
of the proposed transaction.
IX. VIOLATION ALLEGED
34. The United States hereby incorporates paragraphs 1 through 33.
35. Defendants' proposed combination of Charter, TWC, and BHN would
likely substantially lessen competition in the numerous geographic
markets for video programming distribution identified above in
violation of Section 7 of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. 18.
36. Unless enjoined, the proposed transactions between Charter,
TWC, and Advance/Newhouse would likely have the following
anticompetitive effects, among others:
a. competition in the development, provision, and sale of video
programming distribution services in each of the relevant geographic
markets will likely be substantially lessened;
b. prices for video programming distribution services will likely
increase to levels above those that would prevail absent the proposed
transactions; and
c. innovation and quality of video programming distribution
services will likely decrease to levels below those that would prevail
absent the proposed transactions.
X. REQUESTED RELIEF
37. Plaintiff United States requests that this Court:
a. adjudge and decree that the proposed transactions violate
Section 7 of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. 18;
b. preliminarily and permanently enjoin the Defendants from
carrying out the proposed transactions, or from entering into or
carrying out any other agreement, understanding, or plan that would
have the effect of bringing the video distribution businesses of
Charter, TWC, and BHN under common ownership or control;
c. award the United States its costs in this action; and
d. award the United States such other and further relief as may be
just and proper.
Dated: April 25, 2016.
Respectfully submitted,
For Plaintiff United States of America:
/s/--------------------------------------------------------------------
Renata B. Hesse (D.C. Bar #466107).
Principal Deputy Assistant Attorney General.
/s/--------------------------------------------------------------------
Patricia A. Brink,
Director of Civil Enforcement.
/s/--------------------------------------------------------------------
Scott A. Scheele (D.C. Bar #429061),
Chief, Telecommunications & Media Enforcement Section.
/s/--------------------------------------------------------------------
Lawrence M. Frankel (D.C. Bar #441532),
Assistant Chief, Telecommunications & Media Enforcement Section.
/s/--------------------------------------------------------------------
Robert A. Lepore*,
Ruediger R. Schuett (D.C. Bar #501174),
Maureen Casey (D.C. Bar #415893),
Trial Attorneys, U.S. Department of Justice, Antitrust Division,
Telecommunications & Media Enforcement Section, 450 Fifth Street
NW., Suite 7000, Washington, DC 20530, Telephone: (202) 532-4928,
Facsimile: (202) 514-6381, Email: Robert.Lepore@usdoj.gov, *Attorney
of Record
UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA
United States of America, Plaintiff, v. Charter Communications,
Inc., Time Warner Cable Inc, Advance/Newhouse Partnership, and
Bright House Networks, LLC, Defendants.
Case No.: 1:16-cv-00759
Judge: Royce C. Lamberth
Filed: 05/10/2016
COMPETITIVE IMPACT STATEMENT
The United States of America (``United States''), pursuant to
Section 2(b) of the Antitrust Procedures and Penalties Act (``APPA'' or
``Tunney Act''), 15 U.S.C. 16(b)-(h), files this Competitive Impact
Statement relating to the proposed Final Judgment submitted for entry
in this civil antitrust proceeding.
I. NATURE AND PURPOSE OF THE PROCEEDING
On May 23, 2015, Charter Communications, Inc. (``Charter'') and
Time Warner Cable, Inc. (``TWC''), two of the largest cable companies
in the United States, agreed to merge in a deal valued at over $78
billion. In addition, Charter and Advance/Newhouse Partnership, which
owns Bright House Networks, LLC (``BHN''), announced that Charter would
acquire BHN for $10.4 billion, conditional on the sale of TWC to
Charter. As a result of these transactions, the combined company,
referred to as ``New Charter,'' will become one of the largest
providers of pay television service in the United States.
The United States filed a civil antitrust Complaint on April 25,
2016, seeking to enjoin the proposed transactions because their likely
effect would be to lessen competition substantially in numerous local
markets for the timely distribution of professional, full-length video
programming to residential customers (``video programming
distribution'') throughout the United States in violation of Section 7
of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. 18. Specifically, the Complaint alleges
that the proposed merger would increase the ability and incentive of
New Charter to use its leverage with video programmers to limit the
access of online video distributors (``OVDs'') to important content.
These OVDs are increasingly offering meaningful competition to cable
companies like Charter, and the loss of competition caused by the
proposed merger likely would result in lower-quality services, fewer
choices, and higher prices for consumers, as well
[[Page 30556]]
as reduced investment and less innovation in this dynamic industry.
At the same time the Complaint was filed, the United States also
filed a Stipulation and proposed Final Judgment, which are designed to
eliminate the anticompetitive effects of the proposed merger. Under the
proposed Final Judgment, which is explained more fully below, the
Defendants will be prohibited from using their bargaining leverage with
video programmers to inhibit the flow of video content to OVDs. The
proposed Final Judgment will provide a prompt, certain, and effective
remedy for consumers by preventing New Charter from using its leverage
over programmers to harm competition. The United States and the
Defendants have stipulated that the proposed Final Judgment may be
entered after compliance with the APPA. Entry of the proposed Final
Judgment would terminate this action, except that the Court would
retain jurisdiction to construe, modify, or enforce the provisions of
the proposed Final Judgment, and to punish and remedy violations
thereof.
The proposed merger was also subject to review and approval by the
Federal Communications Commission (``FCC'').\1\ On May 5, 2016, the FCC
adopted an order approving the transactions subject to certain
conditions discussed below, and that order was released publicly on May
10, 2016. The Department and the FCC coordinated closely in their
reviews of the proposed merger. The FCC's remedy is independent of the
proposed Final Judgment and not subject to review in this proceeding.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1\ Under the Communications Act, the FCC has jurisdiction to
determine whether mergers involving the transfer of a
telecommunications license are in the ``public interest,
convenience, and necessity.'' 47 U.S.C. 310(d).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
II. DESCRIPTION OF THE EVENTS GIVING RISE TO THE ALLEGED VIOLATION
A. The Defendants and the Proposed Merger
Charter is the third-largest cable company in the United States,
and the sixth-largest multichannel video programming distributor
(``MVPD'') overall. Charter owns cable systems across 28 states,
serving approximately 4.8 million residential broadband customers and
4.2 million residential video customers. Charter reported total
revenues of around $9.1 billion in 2014, approximately $4.4 billion of
which were derived from Charter's video business.
TWC is the second-largest cable company in the United States
(behind only Comcast Corp.), and the fourth-largest MVPD in the
country. TWC's cable systems serve approximately 11.7 million
residential broadband and 10.8 million residential video customers in
30 states. TWC reported total revenues of approximately $22.8 billion
in 2014, around $10.4 billion of which were derived from TWC's video
business.
BHN is the sixth-largest incumbent cable company in the United
States and the ninth-largest MVPD overall. It owns cable systems
serving approximately 2 million video customers across six states, the
majority of whom are located in the Orlando and Tampa-St. Petersburg,
Florida areas. BHN is a wholly-owned subsidiary of Advance/Newhouse
Partnership. Although the Advance/Newhouse Partnership retains the
authority to manage BHN, it has entered into agreements by which TWC
performs certain functions for BHN, including the procurement of cable
programming. In 2014, BHN generated total revenues of around $3.7
billion, approximately $1.5 billion of which were derived from its
video business.
The proposed transactions combining Charter, TWC, and BHN into New
Charter, as initially agreed to by the Defendants on May 23, 2015,
would lessen competition substantially in numerous local markets for
video programming distribution. These transactions are the subject of
the Complaint and proposed Final Judgment filed by the United States on
April 25, 2016.
B. The Structure of the Video Programming Distribution Industry
The video programming distribution industry operates at two
distinct levels. At the ``upstream'' level, video programmers license
their content to video programming distributors--both OVDs and
traditional MVPDs including Charter, TWC, and BHN. At the
``downstream'' level, the video programming distributors then sell
subscriptions to various packages of that content and deliver the
content to residential customers.
[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN17MY16.335
1. Video Programmers
Video programmers produce themselves, or acquire from other
copyright holders, a collection of professional, full-length programs
and movies. These video programmers then typically aggregate this
content into branded networks (e.g., NBC or The History Channel) that
provide a 24-hour schedule that is attractive to consumers. Large video
programmers often own multiple individual networks. For instance, The
Walt Disney Company owns the ABC broadcast network as
[[Page 30557]]
well as many cable networks such as ESPN and The Disney Channel.
In order to acquire the rights to distribute each network, video
programming distributors pay the video programmer a license fee,
generally on a per-subscriber basis. These license fees are an
important revenue stream for video programmers. Most of the remainder
of their revenues comes from fees for advertisements placed on their
networks.
Video programmers rely on video programming distributors--both
MVPDs and OVDs--to reach consumers. Unless a video programmer obtains
carriage in the packages of video programming distributors that reach a
sufficient number of consumers, the programmers will be unable to earn
enough revenue in licensing or to attract enough advertising revenue to
generate a return on their investments in content. For this reason,
video programmers prefer to have as many video programming distributors
as possible carry their networks, and particularly seek out the largest
MVPDs that reach the most customers. If the programmer is unable to
agree on acceptable terms with a particular distributor, the
programmer's content will not be available to that distributor's
customers. This potential consequence gives the largest MVPDs
significant bargaining leverage in their negotiations with programmers.
2. Multichannel Video Programming Distributors
Traditional video programming distributors include incumbent cable
companies such as Charter and TWC; direct broadcast satellite (``DBS'')
providers such as DirecTV and DISH Network; telephone companies
(``telcos'') that offer video services such as Verizon and AT&T; and
overbuilders such as Google Fiber and RCN.\2\ These distributors are
referred to collectively as MVPDs. MVPDs typically offer hundreds of
channels of professional video programming to residential customers for
a monthly subscription fee.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\2\ Overbuilders are providers who have constructed an
additional wired network to residential consumers for offering video
and broadband service (i.e., they have ``built over'' the cable and
phone company networks).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
3. Online Video Programming Distributors
OVDs are relatively recent entrants into the video programming
distribution market. They deliver a variety of live and/or on-demand
video programming over the Internet, whether streamed to Internet-
connected televisions or other devices, or downloaded for later
viewing. OVDs today include services like Netflix, Hulu, Amazon Prime
Instant Video, and Sling TV, although, as discussed in more detail
below, their content selection and business models vary greatly. Unlike
MVPDs, OVDs do not own distribution facilities and are dependent upon
broadband Internet access service providers, including incumbent cable
companies such as Charter and TWC, for the delivery of their content to
viewers.
C. The Relevant Market and Market Concentration
The Complaint alleges that video programming distribution
constitutes a relevant product market and line of commerce under
Section 7 of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. 18. The market for video
programming distribution includes both traditional MVPDs and their
newer OVD rivals.
Consumers purchase video programming distribution services from
among those distributors that can offer such services directly to their
home. The DBS operators, DirecTV and DISH, can reach almost any
customer in the continental United States who has an unobstructed line
of sight to their satellites. OVDs are available to any consumer with
an Internet service sufficient to deliver video of an acceptable
quality. In contrast, wireline-based distributors such as cable
companies and telcos generally must obtain a franchise from local,
municipal, or state authorities in order to construct and operate a
wireline network in a specific area, and then build lines to homes in
that area. A consumer cannot purchase video programming distribution
services from a wireline distributor operating outside its franchise
area because the distributor does not have the facilities to reach the
consumer's home. Thus, although the set of video programming
distributors able to offer service to individual consumers' residences
is generally the same within each local community, the set can differ
from one local community to another.
According to the Complaint, each local community whose residents
face the same competitive choices in video programming distribution
comprises a geographic market and section of the country under Section
7 of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. 18. The geographic markets relevant to
this action are the numerous local markets throughout the United States
where either Charter, TWC, or BHN is the incumbent cable operator--an
area encompassing 48 million U.S. television households located across
41 states. However, because OVDs typically offer services nationwide,
the Complaint alleges that anticompetitive effects of the proposed
merger likely extend to the entire United States.
The incumbent cable companies are often the largest video
distribution provider in their respective local territories; the
Defendants' market shares, for example, exceed 50 percent in many local
markets in which they operate. The DBS providers, DirecTV and DISH
Network, account for an average of about one third of video programming
subscribers combined in any given local market. The telcos, including
AT&T and Verizon, have market shares as high as 40 percent in the
communities they have entered, but they are only available in limited
areas and account for about 10 percent of video programming customers
nationwide. Overbuilders such as Google Fiber can also have moderately
high shares in particular local markets, but their services are only
available in a small number of areas and they account for fewer than
two percent of nationwide video programming distribution subscribers.
Although OVDs have acquired a significant number of customers over
the last several years, most of these customers also purchase
traditional MVPD subscriptions. As a result, OVDs currently have a
small share of video programming distribution market revenues--likely
around 5%.
D. Emerging Competition From OVDs in the Relevant Market
1. OVD Business Models and Participants
OVDs have developed a number of different business models for
delivering content to consumers. Several OVDs, including Netflix,
Amazon Prime Instant Video, and Hulu Plus, offer ``subscription video
on demand'' (``SVOD'') services where consumers typically obtain access
to a wide library of movies, past-season television shows, and original
content for a subscription fee.\3\ In addition, some individual cable
programmers, such as CBS and HBO, have begun offering their content
directly to consumers on an SVOD basis. For example, HBO's service,
branded HBO NOW, provides subscribers who pay a monthly fee with access
to the same HBO content over the Internet that they would receive
through a subscription to HBO as part of an MVPD package.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\3\ Hulu also offers current-season content from various
television networks on an ad-supported basis for no subscription
fee.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
In contrast to these SVOD providers, a few OVDs have recently begun
[[Page 30558]]
offering MVPD-like bundles of live, scheduled content to consumers over
the Internet. In early 2015, DISH launched Sling TV, a monthly
subscription service that provides customers access to many of the same
cable networks that are available through traditional MVPDs. Sony has
launched a similar service called PlayStation Vue. Unlike SVODs, these
``virtual'' MVPDs (``vMVPDs'') provide customers the ability to watch
live sports and news programming, as well as other scheduled
entertainment programming, at the same time it is available on
traditional MVPDs.
2. The Effects of OVD Development on Traditional MVPDs
As OVDs have developed new business models and obtained a wider
array of attractive video content, they have started to become closer
substitutes for traditional MVPD services. Although many consumers
treat OVD services as a complement to traditional MVPD service--for
example, purchasing services from an SVOD like Netflix to access past
season content and Netflix's original content but subscribing to an
MVPD for live and current-season content--some are already using OVDs
as substitutes for at least a portion of their video consumption. These
consumers buy smaller content packages from traditional MVPDs, decline
to take certain premium channels, or purchase fewer VOD offerings, and
instead substitute content from OVDs, a practice known as ``cord-
shaving.'' In addition, a small, but growing number of MVPD customers
are ``cutting the cable cord'' completely, using one or more OVDs as a
replacement for their MVPD service. Finally, some younger consumers are
emerging as ``cord nevers'' who do not seek out an MVPD subscription in
the first place.
Absent interference from the established MVPDs, OVDs are likely to
continue to grow, and to become stronger competitors to MVPDs.
Moreover, to the extent that OVDs continue to develop services that
more closely resemble those offered by traditional MVPDs, such as the
live programming offered by vMVPDs or the current season content
offered by certain SVODs, traditional MVPDs will likely face greater
substitution to OVD services. To this end, the Defendants' internal
documents show that they have typically been comparatively less
concerned about competition from certain SVOD providers, like Netflix,
that do not offer live or current-season programming, and more
concerned by the threat posed by vMVPDs like Sling TV and SVODs like
HBO NOW that offer current season content.
3. Traditional MVPDs' Responses to the Growth of OVDs
The Defendants and many other MVPDs recognize the threat that the
growth of OVDs pose to their video distribution businesses. Numerous
internal documents reflect the Defendants' assessment that OVDs are
growing quickly and pose a competitive threat to traditional forms of
video programming distribution. MVPDs have responded to this growth in
various ways. To keep their customers from migrating some or all of
their viewing to OVDs, many MVPDs, including the Defendants, have
introduced new and less expensive packages with smaller numbers of
channels, increased the amount of content available on an on-demand
basis, and made content available to subscribers on devices other than
traditional cable set-top boxes. At the same time, however, some MVPDs
have sought to restrain nascent OVD competition directly by exercising
their leverage over video programmers to restrict video programmers'
ability to license content to OVDs. As alleged in the Complaint, and
explained in more detail below, TWC has been an industry leader in
seeking such restrictions, and the formation of New Charter will create
an entity with an increased ability and incentive to do so.
E. The Anticompetitive Effects of the Proposed Merger
Although Defendants do not compete to provide video distribution
services to consumers in the same local geographic markets, the Clayton
Act is also concerned with mergers that threaten to reduce the number
or quality of choices available to consumers by increasing the merging
parties' incentive or ability to engage in conduct that would foreclose
competition.\4\ For example, a merger may create, or substantially
enhance, the ability or incentive of the merged firm to protect its
market power by denying or raising the price of an input to the firm's
rivals.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\4\ See Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294, 317
(1962) (noting that the Clayton Act intended to make illegal ``not
only [] mergers between actual competitors, but also [] vertical and
conglomerate mergers whose effect may tend to lessen competition in
any line of commerce in any section of the country.''); FTC v.
Procter & Gamble Co., 386 U.S. 568, 577 (1967) (``All mergers are
within the reach of Sec. 7, and all must be tested by the same
standard, whether they are classified as horizontal, vertical,
conglomerate.'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
As alleged in the Complaint, New Charter will be significantly
larger than each of the Defendants individually, and thus will have a
greater incentive and ability to use its bargaining power with video
programmers to protect its market power in the local markets for video
programming distribution. Specifically, following the merger, New
Charter will be the one of the largest MVPDs in the country, with over
17 million subscribers in 41 states, and will therefore be a critical
distribution channel for video programmers. The Complaint alleges that
this greater scale will give New Charter more leverage to demand that
programmers agree to limit their distribution to OVDs, enabling the
merged firm to increase barriers to entry for OVDs or otherwise make
OVDs less competitive.
The Complaint also alleges that New Charter will have increased
incentive to engage in such behavior because it will stand to lose
substantially more profits than Charter, TWC, and BHN individually if
OVDs take business from traditional MVPDs, and it will internalize more
of the benefits of harming OVDs. The Defendants' specific means for
foreclosing OVDs--ADM clauses and other restrictive contracting
provisions--are discussed in more detail below.
1. TWC Is the Industry Leader in Imposing ADMs and Other Restrictive
Programming Clauses that Limit Video Programmers' Rights to License to
OVDs
Video programmers sign lengthy licensing agreements with
distributors that establish the terms on which the distributors will
carry the programmers' networks. Sometimes, these licensing agreements
include restrictions on the other distributors to whom the programmer
may license content, or on other ways the programmer may make the
content available to consumers. One type of restriction is often
referred to in the industry as an ``alternative distribution means''
(``ADM'') clause. ADM clauses take many forms, and in some cases can
have significant consequences for programmers' ability to license to
OVDs. For example, some ADMs prohibit a video programmer from licensing
content to OVDs for an extended period of time after the content is
first aired on traditional MVPDs--permanently blocking OVDs from being
able to offer current-season content from those programmers. Other ADMs
prohibit the programmer from licensing content to OVDs unless the OVDs
meet a number of strict (and sometimes elaborate) criteria that can be
difficult to satisfy.\5\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\5\ For instance, an ADM in one MVPD's contract with a video
programmer prohibited the programmer from licensing to any OVD
unless that OVD offered a package that included thirty-five
channels, including at least two channels each from three out of a
list of six large video programmers.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
[[Page 30559]]
TWC has been the most aggressive MVPD at seeking and obtaining
restrictive ADM clauses in recent years. The Department's review of
hundreds of programming contracts and ordinary course business
documents revealed that TWC has obtained numerous ADMs that limit
distribution to paid OVDs. Other distributors, by contrast, have
rarely, if ever, sought or obtained such clauses, or have only obtained
ADMs that are much less restrictive. TWC's success in seeking and
obtaining ADMs is likely attributable in part to its bargaining
leverage over video programmers; although such programmers might
disfavor such restrictions because they require the programmer to
forsake opportunities to earn revenues from OVDs, they are more likely
to agree to a large MVPD such as TWC's demand to include them because
they do not want to lose access to TWC's millions of cable subscribers.
The Department's investigation further suggested that TWC may be
the most aggressive at obtaining such clauses because, other than
Comcast, TWC has more to lose from the expansion of OVDs than any other
traditional MVPD. Although Comcast also has substantial video profits
at risk, it is prohibited from entering into or enforcing any
provisions that restrict distribution to OVDs under the terms of a
consent decree entered in United States v. Comcast Corp.\6\ By
contrast, distributors with fewer subscribers than TWC have less to
lose from the expansion of OVDs, and, in some cases, may actually
support OVD expansion because they make little or no profit margin on
their video distribution businesses and would prefer to improve the
attractiveness of their broadband Internet access services. Meanwhile,
the two DBS providers, DISH and DirecTV, have historically been
comparable to TWC in size, but because of their different distribution
technology and their customer demographics, may perceive a lower threat
from OVDs. In fact, DISH is offering an OVD service of its own--Sling
TV--and DirecTV recently announced plans to offer a similar OVD
service.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\6\ See Final Judgment, United States et al. v. Comcast et al.,
Civil Action No. 1:11cv-00106, 2011-2 Trade Cas. (CCH) ]77,585, 2011
WL 5402137 (D.D.C. Sept. 1, 2011), available at https://www.justice.gov/atr/case-document/file/492196/download.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
2. The Proposed Transaction Increases New Charter's Ability and
Incentive To Obtain ADMs and Other Restrictive Programming Clauses
The number and scope of the ADMs that TWC obtained prior to the
merger suggests that TWC believes that these ADM clauses are worth
whatever consideration it must provide video programmers in return.
After the merger, New Charter, with over 17 million video subscribers
in 41 states, will have even more leverage than TWC to demand that
programmers agree to ADMs. Given the importance of New Charter as a
distribution channel, programmers will be less likely to risk losing
access to New Charter's considerable subscriber base--which is almost
60 percent larger than TWC alone--and will be more likely to accept to
New Charter's demands. Moreover, since New Charter will have far more
profits at risk from increased OVD competition than Charter, TWC, or
BHN standing alone, it will be willing to provide greater consideration
to programmers to obtain such clauses. As a result, New Charter can be
expected to seek and obtain ADMs with more programmers than TWC has to
date, and the ADMs are likely to be more restrictive than TWC's current
ADM provisions. As alleged in the Complaint, such ADMs could negatively
affect OVDs' business models and undermine their ability to provide
robust video offerings that compete with the offerings of traditional
MVPDs. The weakening of OVD competition will result in lower-quality
services, fewer consumer choices, and higher prices.
4. Entry Is Unlikely To Reverse the Anticompetitive Effects of the
Proposed Merger
Successful entry into the traditional video programming
distribution business is difficult and requires an enormous upfront
investment to create a distribution infrastructure. As alleged in the
Complaint, additional entry into wireline or DBS distribution is not
likely to be significant for the next several years. Telcos have been
willing to incur some of the enormous costs to modify their existing
telephone infrastructure to distribute video, and will continue to do
so, but only in certain areas. Other new providers, such as Google
Fiber, are also expanding services, but the time and expense required
to build to each new area makes expansion slow. Therefore, traditional
MVPDs' market shares are likely to be fairly stable over the next
several years.
OVDs represent the most likely prospect for successful and
significant competitive entry into the existing video programming
distribution market. However, in addition to the other barriers they
face, OVDs must obtain access to a sufficient amount of content to
become viable distribution businesses, and the proposed merger will
likely increase that barrier to entry even further.
III. EXPLANATION OF THE PROPOSED FINAL JUDGMENT
The proposed Final Judgment ensures that New Charter will not
impede competition by using programming contracts to prevent the flow
of content to OVDs. The proposed Final Judgment thereby protects
consumers by eliminating the likely anticompetitive effects of the
proposed merger alleged in the Complaint.
A. The Proposed Final Judgment Prohibits Defendants From Limiting
Distribution to OVDs Through Restrictive Licensing Practices
As discussed above, certain types of contract provisions, such as
ADMs, can have the purpose and effect of limiting distribution to OVDs.
However, not all provisions that limit distribution are
anticompetitive. Reflecting this reality, Sections IV.A and IV.B of the
proposed Final Judgment set forth broad prohibitions on restrictive
contracting practices, while Section IV.C delineates a narrowly
tailored set of exceptions. Taken together, these provisions ensure
that New Charter cannot use restrictive contract terms to harm the
development of OVDs, but preserve programmers' incentives to produce
quality programming and New Charter's ability to compete with other
distributors to obtain marquee content.
Section IV.A of the proposed Final Judgment prohibits New Charter
from entering into or enforcing agreements that forbid, limit, or
create incentives to limit the provision of video programming to OVDs.
This language prevents New Charter from enforcing the ADM provisions in
current TWC contracts, or from entering into new provisions.
Section IV.B provides additional detail as to the types of terms
that could create ``incentives to limit'' distribution to OVDs. The
Department's investigation revealed that TWC has obtained ADM
provisions for the purpose of attempting to limit distribution to OVDs.
However, once those agreements are prohibited, New Charter could
substitute ADMs with more subtle types of contract provisions that do
not directly limit distribution to
[[Page 30560]]
OVDs, but make it financially unattractive for video programmers to
license content to OVDs. For instance, absent relief, New Charter could
enter into an agreement that permits a video programmer to license
content to an OVD, but specifies that so licensing will entitle New
Charter to a massive license fee discount. To prevent evasion of the
ban on ADMs, Section IV.B.1 clarifies that such ``penalty'' provisions
that create incentives to limit distribution to OVDs are not permitted.
Alternatively, New Charter could enter into certain kinds of ``most
favored nation'' (``MFN'') provisions that are designed to create
incentives to limit distribution to OVDs. Although MFN provisions are
ubiquitous in the industry--for example, many MVPDs use MFN provisions
entitling the MVPD to the lowest license fee that the programmer offers
to any other MVPD--the Department's investigation revealed that some
MVPDs were utilizing certain provisions that, while referred to as
``MFNs,'' actually require much more than equal treatment.
Specifically, some provisions, commonly referred to as ``unconditional
MFNs'' or ``cherry-picking MFNs,'' require that a programmer provide an
MVPD the most favorable term the programmer has offered to any other
distributor, even if that other distributor agreed to additional
payment or other conditions in exchange for receiving that term.\7\ As
a result of an unconditional MFN, the programmer may be reluctant to
license the additional content to the other distributor in the first
place.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\7\ For example, a programmer may enter into an agreement with
Distributor A that provides Distributor A with extra content (for
instance, additional video-on-demand rights) in exchange for an
extra payment. If the programmer has an unconditional MFN with
Distributor B, the programmer may then be required to provide the
additional video-on-demand rights to Distributor B without
Distributor B having to make the extra payment. By contrast, a more
typical--and less problematic--MFN would entitle Distributor B to
the additional content only if Distributor B agreed to pay the same
additional fee paid by Distributor A.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Although unconditional MFNs are uncommon today, and the Defendants
have only a few such provisions in their current contracts, the
Department was concerned that New Charter could replace ADMs with
unconditional MFNs in an effort to circumvent the proposed Final
Judgment. For example, New Charter might obtain an unconditional MFN
from a programmer that would entitle New Charter to receive at no
additional cost any content a programmer makes available to an OVD,
regardless of payments or other conditions with which the OVD must
comply. In such case, by providing programming to an OVD, the
programmer might face significant economic disadvantages in the form of
losing the opportunity to monetize the content through distribution by
New Charter. As a result, unconditional MFNs could create significant
disincentives for programmers to license content to OVDs. For these
reasons, Section IV.B.2 of the proposed Final Judgment prohibits New
Charter from entering into or enforcing unconditional MFNs against
programmers for distributing their content to OVDs.\8\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\8\ Specifically, Section IV.B.2.i provides that New Charter may
not require a programmer to provide New Charter the same terms
offered to an OVD unless New Charter also accepts any conditions
that are integrally related, logically linked, or directly tied to
those terms. The language chosen for this provision mirrors language
that is common in conditional MFN provisions throughout the
industry. Also consistent with other conditional MFNs in the
industry, Section IV.B.2.ii states that Charter need not comply with
related terms and conditions if it is unable to do so for
technological or regulatory reasons.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Section IV.C of the proposed Final Judgment establishes three
narrow exceptions to the broad prohibitions in Sections IV.A and IV.B.
First, New Charter may prohibit the programmer from making content
available on the Internet for free for 30 days after its initial
airing, if New Charter has paid a fee for the video programming. The
Department's investigation revealed that such limitations on free
distribution are ubiquitous in the industry, and the Department has
discovered no evidence that such provisions are harmful to competition.
Second, New Charter may enter into an agreement in which the
programmer provides content exclusively to New Charter, and to no other
MVPD or OVD. Although uncommon, a few programmers wish to make some of
their content available to only one distributor. This relationship then
incentivizes the distributor to vigorously market the content, and thus
can be procompetitive in some circumstances. The proposed Final
Judgment ensures that New Charter can continue to compete with other
distributors to obtain these kinds of exclusives. As long as the
exclusivity applies to all other video programming distributors, and
does not narrowly prohibit distribution only to OVDs, the Department
has no basis to believe such provisions will always or usually be
harmful.\9\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\9\ The Department retains the authority to challenge under
Sections 1 or 2 of the Sherman Act any exclusive agreement in the
future that the evidence demonstrates unreasonably restrains trade
or creates or enhances monopoly power. See Proposed Final Judgment
at Sec. VII (No Limitation of Government Rights).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Third, New Charter may condition carriage of programming on its
cable system on terms which require it to receive as favorable material
terms as other MVPDs or OVDs, except to the extent such terms would be
inconsistent with the purpose of the proposed Final Judgment. That is,
New Charter may enter into the kinds of ordinary conditional MFNs that
are ubiquitous in the industry, such as a provision which entitles New
Charter to the lowest license fee paid by any other distributor. This
provision explicitly does not override Section IV.B.2's ban on the
application of unconditional MFNs to OVD distribution. Importantly, New
Charter may not use MFNs as a back door to obtain provisions which are
otherwise ``inconsistent with the purpose of Sections A and B.'' For
instance, even if another distributor obtains a provision which
``create[s] incentives to limit'' a programmer's provision of
programming to an OVD, New Charter cannot use an MFN to add that other
distributor's provision to New Charter's own contract.
2. The Proposed Final Judgment Prohibits Defendants From Discriminating
Against, Retaliating Against, or Punishing Video Programmers
Section IV.D of the proposed Final Judgment prohibits Defendants
from discriminating against, retaliating against, or punishing any
Video Programmer for providing programming to any OVD. This provision
ensures that even though Defendants are no longer permitted to
contractually prohibit or deter video programmers from licensing
content to OVDs, the Defendants are not able to instead deter such
licensing through threats or punishment. Section IV.D also prohibits
Defendants from discriminating against, retaliating against, or
punishing any video programmer for invoking any provisions of the
proposed Final Judgment or any FCC rule or order, or for furnishing
information to the Department concerning Defendants' compliance with
the proposed Final Judgment.
Negotiations between video programmers and MVPDs are often
contentious, high-stakes affairs, and it is common for one or both
sides to the negotiation to threaten to walk away, or even to
temporarily terminate the relationship (sometimes called a ``blackout''
or ``going dark'') in order to secure a better deal. The proposed Final
Judgment is not concerned with such negotiating tactics and therefore
clarifies that ``[p]ursuing a more advantageous deal with a Video
Programmer does not constitute discrimination, retaliation, or
[[Page 30561]]
punishment.'' Rather, Section IV.D is designed to prevent situations
where New Charter intentionally decides to forgo an agreement with a
programmer that would otherwise be economical for New Charter in order
to obtain the long-term benefits of deterring video programmers from
licensing content to OVDs or cooperating with the Department or the
FCC.
3. Provision of Defendants' FCC Interconnection Reports
Although the Department's Complaint focuses on the likely
competitive harm resulting from New Charter's imposition of ADMs and
other contractual restrictions on video programmers, the Department
also investigated the potential for the proposed merger to increase the
price New Charter will charge Internet content companies, including
OVDs, for access to its broadband subscribers. OVDs rely on broadband
connections provided by other companies to reach their customers, and
the Defendants are also major providers of Internet access service.
Therefore, the Department examined whether the merger could increase
both the incentive and ability of New Charter to use its control over
the interconnection to New Charter's broadband Internet service
provider network to try and disadvantage online video competitors.
The FCC's order approving the merger imposes an obligation on New
Charter to make interconnection available on a non-discriminatory,
settlement-free basis to any Internet content provider, transit
provider, or content delivery network (``CDN'') who meets certain basic
criteria. Although this policy only directly protects those sending
large volumes of traffic, even smaller sources who do not qualify for
direct interconnection ought to find ample bandwidth available at
competitive prices because large transit and CDN providers will be
guaranteed access, and could resell that capacity. Thus, the Department
expects that the FCC's order will prevent any merger-related harm to
Internet content companies, including OVDs. In light of the FCC's
remedy, the Department did not target interconnection in its Complaint
and elected not to pursue duplicative relief with respect to
interconnection in the proposed Final Judgment. However, in order to
assist the Department in monitoring future developments with regard to
interconnection and in taking whatever action might be appropriate to
prevent anticompetitive conduct, Section IV.E requires New Charter to
provide the Department with copies of the regular reports that New
Charter furnishes to the FCC pursuant to the FCC's order.
D. Term of the Proposed Final Judgment
Section VIII of the proposed Final Judgment provides that the Final
Judgment will expire seven years from the date of entry. The Department
believes this time period is long enough to ensure that New Charter
cannot harm OVD competitors at a crucial point in their development
while accounting for the rapidly evolving nature of the video
distribution market. After five years, Section VIII permits Charter to
request that the Department reevaluate whether the Final Judgment
remains necessary to protect competition. If at such time the
Department concludes that the market has evolved such that the
protections of the decree are no longer necessary, it will recommend to
the Court that the Final Judgment be terminated.
IV. REMEDIES AVAILABLE TO POTENTIAL PRIVATE LITIGANTS
Section 4 of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. 15, provides that any
person who has been injured as a result of conduct prohibited by the
antitrust laws may bring suit in federal court to recover three times
the damages the person has suffered, as well as costs and reasonable
attorneys' fees. Entry of the proposed Final Judgment will neither
impair nor assist the bringing of any private antitrust damage action.
Under the provisions of Section 5(a) of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C.
16(a), the proposed Final Judgment has no prima facie effect in any
subsequent private lawsuit that may be brought against Defendants.
V. PROCEDURES AVAILABLE FOR MODIFICATION OF THE PROPOSED FINAL JUDGMENT
The United States and Defendants have stipulated that the proposed
Final Judgment may be entered by the Court after compliance with the
provisions of the APPA, provided that the United States has not
withdrawn its consent. The APPA conditions entry upon the Court's
determination that the proposed Final Judgment is in the public
interest.
The APPA provides a period of at least 60 days preceding the
effective date of the proposed Final Judgment within which any person
may submit to the United States written comments regarding the proposed
Final Judgment. Any person who wishes to comment should do so within 60
days of the date of publication of this Competitive Impact Statement in
the Federal Register, or the last date of publication in a newspaper of
the summary of this Competitive Impact Statement, whichever is later.
All comments received during this period will be considered by the
United States, which remains free to withdraw its consent to the
proposed Final Judgment at any time prior to the Court's entry of
judgment. The comments and the response of the United States will be
filed with the Court. In addition, comments will be posted on the U.S.
Department of Justice, Antitrust Division's internet Web site and,
under certain circumstances, published in the Federal Register. Written
comments should be submitted to:
Scott A. Scheele
Chief, Telecommunications and Media Enforcement Section
Antitrust Division
United States Department of Justice
450 Fifth Street NW., Suite 7000
Washington, DC 20530
The proposed Final Judgment provides that the Court retains
jurisdiction over this action, and the parties may apply to the Court
for any order necessary or appropriate for the modification,
interpretation, or enforcement of the Final Judgment.
VI. ALTERNATIVES TO THE PROPOSED FINAL JUDGMENT
The United States considered, as an alternative to the proposed
Final Judgment, seeking preliminary and permanent injunctions against
Defendants' transactions and proceeding to a full trial on the merits.
The United States is satisfied, however, that the relief in the
proposed Final Judgment will preserve competition for the provision of
video programming distribution services in the United States. Thus, the
proposed Final Judgment would protect competition as effectively as
would any remedy available through litigation, but avoids the time,
expense, and uncertainty of a full trial on the merits.
VII. STANDARD OF REVIEW UNDER THE APPA FOR THE PROPOSED FINAL JUDGMENT
The Clayton Act, as amended by the APPA, requires that proposed
consent judgments in antitrust cases brought by the United States be
subject to a sixty-day comment period, after which the court shall
determine whether entry of the proposed Final Judgment ``is in the
public interest.'' 15 U.S.C. 16(e)(1). In making that determination,
the court, in accordance with the statute as amended in 2004, is
required to consider:
(A) the competitive impact of such judgment, including
termination of alleged violations, provisions for enforcement and
modification, duration of relief sought,
[[Page 30562]]
anticipated effects of alternative remedies actually considered,
whether its terms are ambiguous, and any other competitive
considerations bearing upon the adequacy of such judgment that the
court deems necessary to a determination of whether the consent
judgment is in the public interest; and
(B) the impact of entry of such judgment upon competition in the
relevant market or markets, upon the public generally and
individuals alleging specific injury from the violations set forth
in the complaint including consideration of the public benefit, if
any, to be derived from a determination of the issues at trial.
15 U.S.C. 16(e)(1)(A) & (B). In considering these statutory factors,
the Court's inquiry is necessarily a limited one as the government is
entitled to ``broad discretion to settle with the defendant within the
reaches of the public interest.'' United States v. Microsoft Corp., 56
F.3d 1448, 1461 (D.C. Cir. 1995); see generally United States v. SBC
Commc'ns, Inc., 489 F. Supp. 2d 1 (D.D.C. 2007) (assessing public
interest standard under the Tunney Act); United States v, U.S. Airways
Group, Inc., 38 F. Supp. 3d 69, 75 (D.D.C. 2014) (explaining that the
``court's inquiry is limited'' in Tunney Act settlements); United
States v. InBev N.V./S.A., No. 08-1965 (JR), 2009-2 Trade Cas. (CCH) ]
76,736, 2009 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 84787, at *3, (D.D.C. Aug. 11, 2009)
(noting that the court's review of a consent judgment is limited and
only inquires ``into whether the government's determination that the
proposed remedies will cure the antitrust violations alleged in the
complaint was reasonable, and whether the mechanism to enforce the
final judgment are clear and manageable.'').\10\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\10\ The 2004 amendments substituted ``shall'' for ``may'' in
directing relevant factors for courts to consider and amended the
list of factors to focus on competitive considerations and to
address potentially ambiguous judgment terms. Compare 15 U.S.C.
16(e) (2004), with 15 U.S.C. 16(e)(1) (2006); see also SBC Commc'ns,
489 F. Supp. 2d at 11 (concluding that the 2004 amendments
``effected minimal changes'' to Tunney Act review).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
As the United States Court of Appeals for the District of Columbia
Circuit has held, under the APPA a court considers, among other things,
the relationship between the remedy secured and the specific
allegations set forth in the government's complaint, whether the decree
is sufficiently clear, whether enforcement mechanisms are sufficient,
and whether the decree may positively harm third parties. See
Microsoft, 56 F.3d at 1458-62. With respect to the adequacy of the
relief secured by the decree, a court may not ``engage in an
unrestricted evaluation of what relief would best serve the public.''
United States v. BNS, Inc., 858 F.2d 456, 462 (9th Cir. 1988) (quoting
United States v. Bechtel Corp., 648 F.2d 660, 666 (9th Cir. 1981)); see
also Microsoft, 56 F.3d at 1460-62; United States v. Alcoa, Inc., 152
F. Supp. 2d 37, 40 (D.D.C. 2001); InBev, 2009 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 84787,
at *3. Courts have held that:
[t]he balancing of competing social and political interests affected
by a proposed antitrust consent decree must be left, in the first
instance, to the discretion of the Attorney General. The court's
role in protecting the public interest is one of insuring that the
government has not breached its duty to the public in consenting to
the decree. The court is required to determine not whether a
particular decree is the one that will best serve society, but
whether the settlement is ``within the reaches of the public
interest.'' More elaborate requirements might undermine the
effectiveness of antitrust enforcement by consent decree.
Bechtel, 648 F.2d at 666 (emphasis added) (citations omitted).\11\ In
determining whether a proposed settlement is in the public interest, a
district court ``must accord deference to the government's predictions
about the efficacy of its remedies, and may not require that the
remedies perfectly match the alleged violations.'' SBC Commc'ns, 489 F.
Supp. 2d at 17; see also U.S. Airways, 38 F. Supp. 3d at 75 (noting
that a court should not reject the proposed remedies because it
believes others are preferable); Microsoft, 56 F.3d at 1461 (noting the
need for courts to be ``deferential to the government's predictions as
to the effect of the proposed remedies''); United States v. Archer-
Daniels-Midland Co., 272 F. Supp. 2d 1, 6 (D.D.C. 2003) (noting that
the court should grant due respect to the United States' prediction as
to the effect of proposed remedies, its perception of the market
structure, and its views of the nature of the case).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\11\ Cf. BNS, 858 F.2d at 464 (holding that the court's
``ultimate authority under the [APPA] is limited to approving or
disapproving the consent decree''); United States v. Gillette Co.,
406 F. Supp. 713, 716 (D. Mass. 1975) (noting that, in this way, the
court is constrained to ``look at the overall picture not
hypercritically, nor with a microscope, but with an artist's
reducing glass''). See generally Microsoft, 56 F.3d at 1461
(discussing whether ``the remedies [obtained in the decree are] so
inconsonant with the allegations charged as to fall outside of the
`reaches of the public interest''').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Courts have greater flexibility in approving proposed consent
decrees than in crafting their own decrees following a finding of
liability in a litigated matter. ``[A] proposed decree must be approved
even if it falls short of the remedy the court would impose on its own,
as long as it falls within the range of acceptability or is `within the
reaches of public interest.''' United States v. Am. Tel. & Tel. Co.,
552 F. Supp. 131, 151 (D.D.C. 1982) (citations omitted) (quoting United
States v. Gillette Co., 406 F. Supp. 713, 716 (D. Mass. 1975)), aff'd
sub nom. Maryland v. United States, 460 U.S. 1001 (1983); see also U.S.
Airways, 38 F. Supp. 3d at 76 (noting that room must be made for the
government to grant concessions in the negotiation process for
settlements (citing Microsoft, 56 F.3d at 1461); United States v. Alcan
Aluminum Ltd., 605 F. Supp. 619, 622 (W.D. Ky. 1985) (approving the
consent decree even though the court would have imposed a greater
remedy). To meet this standard, the United States ``need only provide a
factual basis for concluding that the settlements are reasonably
adequate remedies for the alleged harms.'' SBC Commc'ns, 489 F. Supp.
2d at 17.
Moreover, the court's role under the APPA is limited to reviewing
the remedy in relationship to the violations that the United States has
alleged in its Complaint, and does not authorize the court to
``construct [its] own hypothetical case and then evaluate the decree
against that case.'' Microsoft, 56 F.3d at 1459; see also U.S. Airways,
38 F. Supp. 3d at 75 (noting that the court must simply determine
whether there is a factual foundation for the government's decisions
such that its conclusions regarding the proposed settlements are
reasonable); InBev, 2009 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 84787, at *20 (``the `public
interest' is not to be measured by comparing the violations alleged in
the complaint against those the court believes could have, or even
should have, been alleged''). Because the ``court's authority to review
the decree depends entirely on the government's exercising its
prosecutorial discretion by bringing a case in the first place,'' it
follows that ``the court is only authorized to review the decree
itself,'' and not to ``effectively redraft the complaint'' to inquire
into other matters that the United States did not pursue. Microsoft, 56
F.3d at 1459-60. As this Court confirmed in SBC Communications, courts
``cannot look beyond the complaint in making the public interest
determination unless the complaint is drafted so narrowly as to make a
mockery of judicial power.'' SBC Commc'ns, 489 F. Supp. 2d at 15.
In its 2004 amendments, Congress made clear its intent to preserve
the practical benefits of utilizing consent decrees in antitrust
enforcement, adding the unambiguous instruction that ``[n]othing in
this section shall be construed to require the court to conduct an
evidentiary hearing or to require the court to permit anyone to
intervene.'' 15 U.S.C. 16(e)(2); see also U.S. Airways, 38 F. Supp. 3d
at 76
[[Page 30563]]
(indicating that a court is not required to hold an evidentiary hearing
or to permit intervenors as part of its review under the Tunney Act).
The language wrote into the statute what Congress intended when it
enacted the Tunney Act in 1974, as Senator Tunney explained: ``[t]he
court is nowhere compelled to go to trial or to engage in extended
proceedings which might have the effect of vitiating the benefits of
prompt and less costly settlement through the consent decree process.''
119 Cong. Rec. 24,598 (1973) (statement of Sen. Tunney). Rather, the
procedure for the public interest determination is left to the
discretion of the court, with the recognition that the court's ``scope
of review remains sharply proscribed by precedent and the nature of
Tunney Act proceedings.'' SBC Commc'ns, 489 F. Supp. 2d at 11.\12\ A
court can make its public interest determination based on the
competitive impact statement and response to public comments alone.
U.S. Airways, 38 F. Supp. 3d at 76.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\12\ See United States v. Enova Corp., 107 F. Supp. 2d 10, 17
(D.D.C. 2000) (noting that the ``Tunney Act expressly allows the
court to make its public interest determination on the basis of the
competitive impact statement and response to comments alone'');
United States v. Mid-Am. Dairymen, Inc., No. 73-CV-681-W-1, 1977-1
Trade Cas. (CCH) ] 61,508, at 71,980, *22 (W.D.
Mo. 1977) (``Absent a showing of corrupt failure of the
government to discharge its duty, the Court, in making its public
interest finding, should . . . carefully consider the explanations
of the government in the competitive impact statement and its
responses to comments in order to determine whether those
explanations are reasonable under the circumstances.''); S. Rep. No.
93-298, at 6 (1973) (``Where the public interest can be meaningfully
evaluated simply on the basis of briefs and oral arguments, that is
the approach that should be utilized.'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
VIII. DETERMINATIVE DOCUMENTS
Appendix B to the FCC's Memorandum Opinion and Order, In re
Applications of Charter Communications, Inc., Time Warner Cable Inc.,
and Advance/Newhouse Partnership for Consent to the Transfer of Control
of Licenses and Authorizations, FCC MB Docket No. 15-149 (adopted May
5, 2016; released May 10, 2016), was the only determinative document or
material within the meaning of the APPA considered by the Department in
formulating the proposed Final Judgment. This document is available on
the FCC's Web site at https://apps.fcc.gov/edocs_public/attachmatch/FCC-16-59A1.pdf, and will also be made available on the Antitrust
Division's Web site at https://www.justice.gov/atr/case/us-v-charter-communications-inc-et-al.
Dated: May 10, 2016
Respectfully submitted,
/s/--------------------------------------------------------------------
Robert A. Lepore,
Telecommunications & Media, Enforcement Section, Antitrust Division,
U.S. Department of Justice, 450 Fifth Street NW., Suite 7000,
Washington, DC 20530, Telephone: (202) 532-4928, Facsimile: (202)
514-6381, Email: Robert.Lepore@usdoj.gov
United States District Court for the District of Columbia
United States of America, Plaintiff, v. Charter Communications,
Inc., Time Warner Cable Inc, Advance/Newhouse Partnership, and
Bright House Networks, LLC, Defendants.
Case No.: 1:16-cv-00759
Judge: Royce C. Lamberth
Filed: 04/25/2016
[PROPOSED] FINAL JUDGMENT
WHEREAS, Plaintiff, the United States of America, filed its
Complaint on April 25, 2016 alleging that Defendants propose to enter
into transactions the likely effect of which would be to lessen
competition substantially in the market for the timely distribution of
professional, full-length video programming to residential customers
(``video programming distribution'') across the United States in
violation of Section 7 of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. 18, and Plaintiff
and Defendants, by their respective attorneys, have consented to the
entry of this Final Judgment without trial or adjudication of any issue
of fact or law, and without this Final Judgment constituting any
evidence against or admission by any party regarding any issue of fact
or law;
AND WHEREAS, Defendants agree to be bound by the provisions of this
Final Judgment pending its approval by the Court;
AND WHEREAS, Plaintiff requires Defendants to agree to undertake
certain actions and refrain from certain conduct for the purpose of
remedying the loss of competition alleged in the Complaint;
AND WHEREAS, Defendants have represented to the United States that
the actions and conduct restrictions can and will be undertaken and
that Defendants will later raise no claim of hardship or difficulty as
grounds for asking the Court to modify any of the provisions contained
below;
NOW THEREFORE, before any testimony is taken, without trial or
adjudication of any issue of fact or law, and upon consent of the
parties, it is ORDERED, ADJUDGED, AND DECREED:
I. JURISDICTION
This Court has jurisdiction over the subject matter of and each of
the parties to this action. The Complaint states a claim upon which
relief may be granted against Defendants under Section 7 of the Clayton
Act, as amended, 15 U.S.C. 18.
II. DEFINITIONS
As used in this Final Judgment:
A. ``Advance/Newhouse'' means defendant Advance/Newhouse
Partnership, a New York partnership with headquarters in East Syracuse,
New York, its successors and assigns, and its Subsidiaries, divisions,
groups, affiliates, partnerships and joint ventures, and their
directors, officers, managers, agents, and employees, in their capacity
as directors, officers, managers, agents, and employees of the
foregoing.
B. ``Bright House'' means defendant Bright House Networks, LLC, a
Delaware limited liability company with headquarters in East Syracuse,
New York, its successors and assigns, and its Subsidiaries, divisions,
groups, affiliates, partnerships and joint ventures, and their
directors, officers, managers, agents, and employees, in their capacity
as directors, officers, managers, agents, and employees of the
foregoing.
C. ``Charter'' means defendant Charter Communications, Inc., a
Delaware corporation with headquarters in Stamford, Connecticut, its
successors and assigns (including, without limitation, CCH I, LLC), and
its Subsidiaries, divisions, groups, affiliates, partnerships and joint
ventures, and their directors, officers, managers, agents, and
employees, in their capacity as directors, officers, managers, agents,
and employees of the foregoing.
D. ``Defendants'' means Charter, TWC, Bright House, and Advance/
Newhouse, acting individually or collectively. Notwithstanding the
foregoing, Advance/Newhouse is not a ``Defendant'' for purposes of
Section IV.
E. ``Department of Justice'' means the United States Department of
Justice Antitrust Division.
F. ``MVPD'' means a multichannel video programming distributor as
that term is defined on the date of entry of this Final Judgment in 47
CFR 76.1200(b), in its capacity as an MVPD.
G. ``OVD'' means any service that (1) distributes Video Programming
in the United States by means of the Internet; (2) is not a component
of an MVPD subscription; and (3) is not solely available to customers
of an Internet access service owned or operated by the Person providing
the service or an affiliate of the Person providing the service. For
avoidance of doubt, this definition (1) includes a service offered by a
Video Programmer for the distribution of its own Video
[[Page 30564]]
Programming by means of the Internet to Persons other than subscribers
of an MVPD service; (2) includes a service offered by an MVPD that
offers Video Programming by means of the Internet outside its MVPD
service territory as a service separate and independent of an MVPD
subscription; and (3) excludes an MVPD that offers Video Programming by
means of the Internet to homes inside its MVPD service territory as a
component of an MVPD subscription.
H. ``Person'' means any natural person, corporation, company,
partnership, joint venture, firm, association, proprietorship, agency,
board, authority, commission, office, or other business or legal
entity, whether private or governmental.
I. ``Subsidiary'' refers to any Person in which there is partial
(25 percent or more) or total ownership or control between the
specified Person and any other Person. Notwithstanding the foregoing,
Subsidiary shall not include any Person in which a Defendant does not
have majority ownership or de facto control if that Person does not
provide MVPD service.
J. ``TWC'' means defendant Time Warner Cable Inc, a New York
corporation with headquarters in New York, New York, its successors and
assigns, and its Subsidiaries, divisions, groups, affiliates,
partnerships and joint ventures, and their directors, officers,
managers, agents, and employees, in their capacity as directors,
officers, managers, agents, and employees of the foregoing.
K. ``Video Programmer'' means any Person that provides Video
Programming for distribution through MVPDs, in its capacity as a Video
Programmer.
L. ``Video Programming'' means programming provided by, or
generally considered comparable to programming provided by, a
television broadcast station or cable network, regardless of the medium
or method used for distribution, and, without expanding the foregoing,
includes programming prescheduled by the programming provider (also
known as scheduled programming or a linear feed); programming offered
to viewers on an on-demand, point-to-point basis (also known as video
on demand); pay per view or transactional video on demand; short
programming segments related to other full-length programming (also
known as clips); programming that includes multiple video sources (also
known as feeds, including camera angles); programming that includes
video in different qualities or formats (including high-definition and
3D); and films for which a year or more has elapsed since their
theatrical release.
III. APPLICABILITY
This Final Judgment applies to Defendants and all other Persons in
active concert or participation with any of them who receive actual
notice of this Final Judgment by personal service or otherwise.
IV. PROHIBITED CONDUCT AND REPORTING
A. Defendants shall not enter into or enforce any agreement with a
Video Programmer under which Defendants forbid, limit, or create
incentives to limit the Video Programmer's provision of its Video
Programming to one or more OVDs.
B. Agreements that ``create incentives to limit'' a Video
Programmer's provision of its Video Programming to one or more OVDs
within the meaning of Section IV.A shall include, but are not limited
to, the following:
1. agreements that provide for any pecuniary or non-pecuniary
penalty on the Video Programmer for the provision of its Video
Programming to an OVD, such as rate reductions, re-tiering or re-
positioning penalties, termination rights for Defendants, or loss or
waiver of any rights or benefits otherwise available to the Video
Programmer; or
2. agreements that entitle Defendants to receive any benefits such
as favorable rates, contract terms, or content rights offered or
granted to an OVD by a Video Programmer without requiring Defendants to
also accept any obligations, limitations, or conditions:
i. that are integrally related, logically linked, or directly tied
to the offering or grant of such rights or benefits, and
ii. with which Defendants can reasonably comply technologically and
legally. For avoidance of doubt, Defendants will be deemed able to
``reasonably comply technologically'' if they are able to implement an
obligation, limitation, or condition in a technologically equivalent
manner.
C. Notwithstanding the foregoing, nothing in this Final Judgment
shall prohibit Defendants from:
1. entering into and enforcing an agreement under which Defendants
discourage or prohibit a Video Programmer from making Video Programming
for which Defendants pay available to consumers for free over the
Internet within the first 30 days after Defendants first distribute the
Video Programming to consumers;
2. entering into and enforcing an agreement under which the Video
Programmer provides Video Programming exclusively to Defendants, and to
no other MVPD or OVD; or
3. entering into and enforcing an agreement which requires that
Defendants receive as favorable material terms as other MVPDs or OVDs,
except to the extent application of other MVPDs' or OVDs' terms would
be inconsistent with the purpose of Sections A and B of this Section
IV.
D. Defendants shall not discriminate against, retaliate against, or
punish any Video Programmer (i) for providing Video Programming to any
MVPD or OVD, (ii) for invoking any provisions of this Final Judgment,
(iii) for invoking the provisions of any rules or orders concerning
Video Programming adopted by the Federal Communications Commission, or
(iv) for furnishing information to the United States concerning
Defendants' compliance or noncompliance with this Final Judgment.
Pursuing a more advantageous deal with a Video Programmer does not
constitute discrimination, retaliation, or punishment.
E. Defendants shall submit to the Department of Justice all reports
and data relating to interconnection with the Defendants' broadband
Internet access network that are required to be submitted to the
Federal Communications Commission (``the Commission'') pursuant to any
rule or order of the Commission, at the same time such reports or data
are required to be submitted to the Commission.
V. COMPLIANCE INSPECTION
A. For purposes of determining or securing compliance with this
Final Judgment, or of determining whether the Final Judgment should be
modified or vacated, and subject to any legally recognized privilege,
from time to time duly authorized representatives of the Department of
Justice, including consultants and other persons retained by the
Department of Justice, shall, upon written request of an authorized
representative of the Assistant Attorney General in charge of the
Antitrust Division, and on reasonable notice to Defendants, be
permitted:
1. access during the Defendants' office hours to inspect and copy,
or at the option of the United States, to require Defendants to provide
to the United States hard copy or electronic copies of, all books,
ledgers, accounts, records, data, and documents in the possession,
custody, or control of Defendants, relating to any matters contained in
this Final Judgment; and
2. to interview, either informally or on the record, the
Defendants' officers, employees, or agents, who may have
[[Page 30565]]
their individual counsel present, regarding such matters. The
interviews shall be subject to the reasonable convenience of the
interviewee and without restraint or interference by Defendants.
B. Upon the written request of an authorized representative of the
Assistant Attorney General in charge of the Antitrust Division,
Defendants shall submit written reports or respond to written
interrogatories, under oath if requested, relating to any of the
matters contained in this Final Judgment as may be requested.
C. No information or documents obtained by the means provided in
this section shall be divulged by the United States to any person other
than an authorized representative of the executive branch of the United
States or the Federal Communications Commission, except in the course
of legal proceedings to which the United States is a party (including
grand jury proceedings), or for the purpose of securing compliance with
this Final Judgment, or as otherwise required by law.
D. If at the time information or documents are furnished by a
Defendant to the United States, the Defendant represents and identifies
in writing the material in any such information or documents to which a
claim of protection may be asserted under Rule 26(c)(1)(G) of the
Federal Rules of Civil Procedure, and the Defendant marks each
pertinent page of such material, ``Subject to claim of protection under
Rule 26(c)(1)(G) of the Federal Rules of Civil Procedure,'' then the
United States shall give the Defendant ten calendar days notice prior
to divulging such material in any civil or administrative proceeding
(other than a grand jury proceeding).
VI. RETENTION OF JURISDICTION
This Court retains jurisdiction to enable any party to apply to
this Court at any time for further orders and directions as may be
necessary or appropriate to carry out or construe this Final Judgment,
to modify any of its provisions, to enforce compliance, and to punish
violations of its provisions.
VII. NO LIMITATION ON GOVERNMENT RIGHTS
Nothing in this Final Judgment shall limit the right of the United
States to investigate and bring actions to prevent or restrain
violations of the antitrust laws concerning any past, present, or
future conduct, policy, or practice of the Defendants.
VIII. EXPIRATION OF FINAL JUDGMENT
This Final Judgment shall expire seven years from the date of its
entry. Notwithstanding the foregoing, the Defendants may request after
five years that the Department of Justice examine competitive
conditions and determine whether the Final Judgment continues to be
necessary to protect competition. If after examination of competitive
conditions the Department of Justice in its sole discretion concludes
that the Final Judgment should be terminated, it will recommend to the
Court that the Final Judgment be terminated.
IX. PUBLIC INTEREST DETERMINATION
Entry of this Final Judgment is in the public interest. The parties
have complied with the requirements of the Antitrust Procedures and
Penalties Act, 15 U.S.C. 16, including making copies available to the
public of this Final Judgment, the Competitive Impact Statement, and
any comments thereon and the United States' responses to comments.
Based upon the record before the Court, which includes the Competitive
Impact Statement and any comments and response to comments filed with
the Court, entry of this Final Judgment is in the public interest.
Date:------------------------------------------------------------------
Court approval subject to procedures set forth in the Antitrust
Procedures and Penalties Act, 15 U.S.C. 16
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
United States District Judge
[FR Doc. 2016-11562 Filed 5-16-16; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 4410-11-P