Promoting the Availability of Diverse and Independent Sources of Video Programming, 10241-10246 [2016-04331]
Download as PDF
Federal Register / Vol. 81, No. 39 / Monday, February 29, 2016 / Notices
on existing state and tribal
bioassessment efforts, with the goal of
collecting comparable data at a limited
number of sites that can be pooled at a
regional level. Pooling data enables
more robust regional analyses and
improves the ability to detect trends
over shorter time periods. This
document describes the development
and implementation of the RMNs. It
includes information on selection of
sites, expectations for data collection,
the rationale for collecting these data,
data infrastructure, and provides
examples of how the RMN data will be
used and analyzed. The report
concludes with a discussion on the
status of monitoring activities and next
steps.
Dated: February 19, 2016.
Mary A. Ross,
Deputy Director, National Center for
Environmental Assessment.
[FR Doc. 2016–04087 Filed 2–26–16; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6560–50–P
ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION
AGENCY
[EPA–HQ–OECA–2011–0239; FRL—9942–
71–OEI]
Information Collection Request
Submitted to OMB for Review and
Approval; Comment Request; NSPS
for Grain Elevators (Renewal)
Environmental Protection
Agency (EPA).
ACTION: Notice.
AGENCY:
The Environmental Protection
Agency has submitted an information
collection request (ICR), ‘‘NSPS for
Grain Elevators (40 CFR part 60, subpart
DD) (Renewal)’’ (EPA ICR No. 1130.11,
OMB Control No. 2060–0082), to the
Office of Management and Budget
(OMB) for review and approval in
accordance with the Paperwork
Reduction Act (44 U.S.C. 3501 et seq.).
This is a proposed extension of the ICR,
which is currently approved through
February 29, 2016. Public comments
were previously requested via the
Federal Register (80 FR 32120) on June
5, 2015 during a 60-day comment
period. This notice allows for an
additional 30 days for public comments.
A fuller description of the ICR is given
below, including its estimated burden
and cost to the public. An Agency may
neither conduct nor sponsor, and a
person is not required to respond to, a
collection of information unless it
displays a currently valid OMB control
number.
asabaliauskas on DSK5VPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
SUMMARY:
VerDate Sep<11>2014
19:23 Feb 26, 2016
Jkt 238001
Additional comments may be
submitted on or before March 30, 2016.
ADDRESSES: Submit your comments,
referencing Docket ID Number EPA–
HQ–OECA–2011–0239, to: (1) EPA
online using www.regulations.gov (our
preferred method), or by email to
docket.oeca@epa.gov, or by mail to: EPA
Docket Center, Environmental
Protection Agency, Mail Code 28221T,
1200 Pennsylvania Ave. NW.,
Washington, DC 20460; and (2) OMB via
email to oira_submission@omb.eop.gov.
Address comments to OMB Desk Officer
for EPA.
EPA’s policy is that all comments
received will be included in the public
docket without change including any
personal information provided, unless
the comment includes profanity, threats,
information claimed to be Confidential
Business Information (CBI) or other
information whose disclosure is
restricted by statute.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
Patrick Yellin, Monitoring, Assistance,
and Media Programs Division, Office of
Compliance, Mail Code 2227A,
Environmental Protection Agency, 1200
Pennsylvania Ave. NW., Washington,
DC 20460; telephone number: (202)
564–2970; fax number: (202) 564–0050;
email address: yellin.patrick@epa.gov.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION:
Supporting documents which explain in
detail the information that the EPA will
be collecting are available in the public
docket for this ICR. The docket can be
viewed online at www.regulations.gov
or in person at the EPA Docket Center,
WJC West, Room 3334, 1301
Constitution Ave. NW., Washington,
DC. The telephone number for the
Docket Center is 202–566–1744. For
additional information about EPA’s
public docket, visit: https://
www.epa.gov/dockets.
Abstract: The New Source
Performance Standards (NSPS) apply to
each affected facility at any grain
terminal elevator or any grain storage
elevator. The facilities are each truck
unloading station, truck loading station,
barge and ship loading station, railcar
loading station, railcar unloading
station, grain dryer and all grain
handling operations that commenced
construction, modification or
reconstruction after August 3, 1978.
Owners or operators of the affected
facilities must make a one-time-only
report of the date of construction or
reconstruction, notification of the actual
date of startup, notification of any
physical or operational change to
existing facility that may increase the
rate of emission of the regulated
pollutant, notification of initial
DATES:
PO 00000
Frm 00037
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
10241
performance test; and results of initial
performance test. Owners or operators
are also required to maintain records of
the occurrence and duration of any
startup, shutdown, or malfunction, or
any period during which the monitoring
system is inoperative.
Form Numbers: None.
Respondents/affected entities: Grain
elevator operations.
Respondent’s obligation to respond:
Mandatory (40 CFR part 60, subpart
DD).
Estimated number of respondents:
200 (total).
Frequency of response: Initially.
Total estimated burden: 460 hours
(per year). Burden is defined at 5 CFR
1320.3(b).
Total estimated cost: $46,000 (per
year). There are no annualized capital/
startup or O&M costs.
Changes in the Estimates: There is a
decrease in the respondent and Agency
burden in this ICR compared to the
previous ICR. This is not due to program
changes. The burden and cost decrease
because we corrected the burden
estimates by removing the annual
summary report line item to more
accurately reflect the Subpart DD
regulatory requirements. The current
Subpart DD NSPS does not impose any
ongoing monitoring or reporting
requirement.
Courtney Kerwin,
Acting Director, Collection Strategies
Division.
[FR Doc. 2016–04241 Filed 2–26–16; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6560–50–P
FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS
COMMISSION
[MB Docket No. 16–41; FCC 16–19]
Promoting the Availability of Diverse
and Independent Sources of Video
Programming
Federal Communications
Commission.
ACTION: Notice of inquiry.
AGENCY:
In this document, the
Commission seeks comment on the
principal issues that independent video
programmers confront in gaining
carriage in the current marketplace and
possible actions the Commission or
others might take to address those
issues. The goal of this proceeding is to
begin a conversation on the state of
independent and diverse programming,
and to assess how the Commission or
others could foster greater consumer
choice and enhance diversity in the
evolving video marketplace by
SUMMARY:
E:\FR\FM\29FEN1.SGM
29FEN1
asabaliauskas on DSK5VPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
10242
Federal Register / Vol. 81, No. 39 / Monday, February 29, 2016 / Notices
eliminating or reducing any barriers
faced by independent programmers in
reaching viewers. The Commission
seeks to explore ways to alleviate such
barriers, as well as its legal authority to
do so.
DATES: Comments are due on or before
March 30, 2016; reply comments are
due on or before April 19, 2016.
ADDRESSES: You may submit comments,
identified by MB Docket No. 16–41, by
any of the following methods:
• Federal eRulemaking Portal: https://
www.regulations.gov. Follow the
instructions for submitting comments.
• Federal Communications
Commission’s Web site: https://
fjallfoss.fcc.gov/ecfs2/. Follow the
instructions for submitting comments.
• Mail: Filings can be sent by hand or
messenger delivery, by commercial
overnight courier, or by first-class or
overnight U.S. Postal Service mail. All
filings must be addressed to the
Commission’s Secretary, Office of the
Secretary, Federal Communications
Commission.
• People with Disabilities: Contact
the FCC to request reasonable
accommodations (accessible format
documents, sign language interpreters,
CART, etc.) by email: FCC504@fcc.gov
or phone: (202) 418–0530 or TTY: (202)
418–0432.
For detailed instructions for
submitting comments and additional
information on the rulemaking process,
see the SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION
section of this document.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: For
additional information on this
proceeding, contact Calisha Myers or
Raelynn Remy of the Policy Division,
Media Bureau at (202) 418–2120 or
Calisha.Myers@fcc.gov; Raelynn.Remy@
fcc.gov.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: This is a
summary of the Commission’s Notice of
Inquiry, FCC 16–19, adopted and
released on February 18, 2016. The full
text is available for public inspection
and copying during regular business
hours in the FCC Reference Center,
Federal Communications Commission,
445 12th Street SW., Room CY–A257,
Washington, DC 20554. This document
will also be available via ECFS at https://
fjallfoss.fcc.gov/ecfs/. Documents will
be available electronically in ASCII,
Microsoft Word, and/or Adobe Acrobat.
The complete text may be purchased
from the Commission’s copy contractor,
445 12th Street SW., Room CY–B402,
Washington, DC 20554. Alternative
formats are available for people with
disabilities (Braille, large print,
electronic files, audio format), by
sending an email to fcc504@fcc.gov or
VerDate Sep<11>2014
19:23 Feb 26, 2016
Jkt 238001
calling the Commission’s Consumer and
Governmental Affairs Bureau at (202)
418–0530 (voice), (202) 418–0432
(TTY).
Synopsis
I. Introduction
1. Over the last quarter century, we
have seen significant changes in the
media landscape that have
fundamentally altered the way in which
Americans access and consume video
programming. When Congress passed
the 1992 Cable Act, the majority of
American households had access to
only one pay television service, and
alternatives to that service were in their
incipient stages. By contrast, consumers
today can access video programming
over multiple competing platforms, and
the dominance of incumbent pay TV
distributors has eroded. However,
incumbent operators retain a very
important position in the video
programming marketplace. Although
competition among video distributors
has grown, traditional multichannel
video programming distributor (MVPD)
carriage is still important for the growth
of many emerging programmers. Some
independent video programmers 1 have
expressed concern that certain carriage
practices of cable operators and other
MVPDs may limit their ability to reach
viewers.
2. A central objective of multichannel
video programming regulation is to
foster a diverse, robust, and competitive
marketplace for the delivery of
multichannel video programming.2 As
the agency charged by statute with
implementing this objective, we seek to
start a fact-finding exercise on the
current state of programming diversity.
Through this NOI, we seek comment on
the principal issues that independent
video programmers confront in gaining
carriage in the current marketplace and
possible actions the Commission or
others might take to address those
issues. Our goal in this proceeding is to
begin a conversation on the state of
independent and diverse programming,
and to assess how the Commission or
others could foster greater consumer
choice and enhance diversity in the
evolving video marketplace by
eliminating or reducing any barriers
faced by independent programmers in
1 For purposes of this proceeding, we define an
‘‘independent video programmer’’ or ‘‘independent
programmer’’ as one that is not vertically integrated
with a MVPD.
2 See, e.g., Telecommunications Act of 1996, Pub
L. 104–104, § 257(b), 110 Stat. 56, 77, (codified at
47 U.S.C. 257(b)); 47 U.S.C. 521; 47 U.S.C. 532(a);
47 U.S.C. 533(f)(2). See also 47 U.S.C. 521(a)(4),
(b)(1) through (5); H.R. No. 102–862, at 2, 1992
U.S.C.C.A.N. 1231, 1232.
PO 00000
Frm 00038
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
reaching viewers. For purposes of this
NOI, we are particularly interested in
starting a dialogue on barriers
experienced by all types of independent
programmers, including small
programmers and new entrants. We seek
to explore ways that the Commission
can alleviate such barriers, as well as its
legal authority to do so. Similar to the
Commission’s exploratory efforts in
other proceedings, we also seek to be
better informed to make any potential
recommendations to other agencies,
Congress, or the private sector, if we
find that solutions to barriers exist that
are beyond the authority of this agency.
We also are interested in addressing
challenges faced by a specific type of
independent programmer—namely,
public, educational, and governmental
(PEG) channels —with respect to MVPD
carriage.
II. Discussion
A. State of the Marketplace for
Independent Programming
3. The Commission seeks information
on the current state of the marketplace
for independent programming and the
availability of such programming to
consumers. Has the number of
independent programmers grown or
decreased? Has the diversity of
programming available to consumers
expanded or contracted? What
percentage of non-broadcast networks
are independent programmers? We also
seek input on the manner in which
independent programmers are carried
by distributors and whether the answers
to the following questions differ for
independent programmers and
vertically integrated programmers. To
what extent are independent
programmers carried by traditional
MVPDs and to what extent are they
carried by over-the-top (OTT) providers?
How many of the independent networks
distributed by MVPDs are also available
on OTT platforms? Is it more difficult
for independent programmers to gain
carriage on certain MVPDs than others
(e.g., cable vs. non-cable MVPDs, or
smaller vs. larger MVPDs)? Does the size
of the MVPD matter? Is there a disparity
in the amount of independent
programming on smaller versus larger
MVPDs? Do large MVPDs have market
power that has an effect on the ability
of independent programmers to obtain
carriage? Conversely, to what extent
does the size of the independent
programmer matter? Do large
independent programmers have an
easier time getting carried than smaller
ones? Are there characteristics of
independent programmers that enable
some to gain MVPD carriage but not
E:\FR\FM\29FEN1.SGM
29FEN1
Federal Register / Vol. 81, No. 39 / Monday, February 29, 2016 / Notices
others? To what extent does the level of
competition among MVPDs impact the
bargaining leverage of independent
programmers in negotiations for carriage
deals? With regard to the foregoing
questions, commenters should provide
examples of and relevant information
regarding specific independent program
networks.
B. Principal Marketplace Obstacles
Faced by Independent Programmers
4. Independent programmers and
others have alleged in various
proceedings that cable operators and
other MVPDs engage in program
carriage practices that hamper the
ability of programmers with limited
bargaining leverage to obtain
distribution of their content. They claim
that these practices deprive consumers
of the benefits of competition, including
greater choice and diversity in
programming content. We seek input
below on several practices that
independent programmers allege have
an adverse impact on them.3
asabaliauskas on DSK5VPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
1. Insistence on Contract Provisions
That Constrain the Ability of
Independent Programmers To Compete
5. Independent programmers and
others have asserted that certain MVPDs
often demand that carriage agreements
include certain contractual provisions,
such as most favored nation (MFN) and
alternative distribution method (ADM)
clauses, that hinder programming
competition, innovation, and diversity.
6. Most Favored Nation Provisions. In
general, MFN provisions entitle the
contracting video programming
distributor to modify a programming
agreement to incorporate more favorable
rates, contract terms, or conditions that
the contracting programmer later agrees
to with another distributor.4 These
3 Pursuant to section 103(c) of the STELA
Reauthorization Act of 2014, the Commission
recently issued a Notice of Proposed Rulemaking to
review the totality of the circumstances test for
evaluating whether broadcast stations and MVPDs
are negotiating for retransmission consent in good
faith. See Implementation of section 103 of the
STELA Reauthorization Act of 2014, Totality of the
Circumstances Test, MB Docket No. 15–216, Notice
of Proposed Rulemaking, 80 FR 59706 (2015)
(Totality of the Circumstances NPRM). Some of the
issues raised in this NOI regarding negotiations
between MVPDs and programmers in general are
similar to issues raised in the Totality of the
Circumstances NPRM. However, we direct parties
wishing to comment on issues relating to
retransmission consent negotiations between
broadcasters and MVPDs to file any comments on
those issues in the Totality of the Circumstances
NPRM docket.
4 MFN rights can be conditional or unconditional.
A conditional MFN provision entitles a distributor
to certain contractual rights that the programmer
has granted to another distributor, as long as the
distributor also accepts equivalent or related terms
and conditions contained in that other distributor’s
VerDate Sep<11>2014
19:23 Feb 26, 2016
Jkt 238001
10243
provisions are the result of contractual
agreements between programmers and
distributors. MFN clauses historically
were used to protect favorable carriage
rates obtained by MVPDs that brought a
large subscriber base to the programmer,
but can be misused to anticompetitive
means in some cases.5 Independent
programmers claim that some MVPDs
increasingly have insisted on MFN
treatment without regard to the
concessions or commitments made by
the programmer to secure those terms
from another MVPD and without
requiring the MVPD to deliver
commensurate value to the programmer.
7. Some parties claim that MVPDs’
insistence on MFN provisions precludes
an independent programmer from
making unique or innovative
arrangements designed to achieve initial
carriage of new programming, because
those same unique terms could then be
required to be extended to all MVPDs.
They further argue that, given the
proliferation of MFN provisions, an
independent programmer that achieves
some carriage is likely to have
numerous MFN obligations, and that
this can initiate a ‘‘domino effect’’ when
a single term in an agreement with one
MVPD or OTT service triggers the MFN
obligations in a programmer’s
agreements with other MVPDs. In
particular, the prospect of having to
make the same concessions to all of the
MVPDs with which an independent
programmer has MFN obligations may
impede the ability of independent
programmers to negotiate carriage
agreements with new-entrant
distributors that have smaller subscriber
bases, such as new OTT distributors. As
a result, programmers and some
advocacy groups claim, some MVPDs
are able to demand MFN concessions
from independent programmers that
make OTT distribution economically
infeasible, which deters independent
programmers from developing new and
innovative types of video programming,
inhibits new distribution models, and
limits the diversity of programming
available to consumers. On the other
hand, some antitrust analyses have
noted that in some situations MFN
provisions may yield benefits, such as
lower prices, reduced transaction costs,
or the development of new products.6
8. We seek comment on the
prevalence and scope of MFNs today in
contracts for carriage of non-broadcast
video programming. Are MFN
provisions included in carriage
contracts between independent
programmers and OTT distributors, or
do they tend to be included only in
MVPD carriage contracts? Are MFN
provisions more often included in
carriage contracts involving
independent programmers than those
involving vertically integrated
programmers? Does the size of the
MVPD or independent programmer
affect whether MFN provisions are
included in carriage contracts? Do MFN
provisions in carriage agreements
between MVPDs and independent
programmers cover the terms of both
other MVPD agreements and OTT
agreements? If so, how often do such
MFN provisions extend to OTT
agreements? Do both cable and noncable MVPDs require MFN provisions?
Do MFN provisions allow MVPDs to
‘‘cherry pick,’’ i.e., to take advantage of
the lower price available in a separate
carriage agreement without a reciprocal
obligation? If so, how often? Will
MVPDs accept some reciprocal
obligations while refusing other
reciprocal obligations?
9. We also seek comment on the costs
and benefits of these provisions. Are
there specific types of MFN provisions
that particularly hinder the creation and
distribution of new or niche
programming? If so, how do those
provisions have this effect? How do
distributors enforce MFN provisions?
Are there specific means of enforcement
that are more common or more onerous
to independent programmers than
others? 7 What benefits are associated
with MFN provisions, and are there
contexts in which the benefits outweigh
any harmful effects of such provisions?
Do MFNs result in lower prices for
consumers? Do they enhance the
likelihood that a start-up independent
programmer will be able to gain carriage
on MVPDs? Do they reduce transaction
costs between MVPDs and independent
programmers? Do independent
programmers receive any consideration,
economic or non-economic, from
agreement. An unconditional MFN provision, by
contrast, contains no such requirement that the
distributor entitled to MFN rights accept equivalent
or related terms and conditions; it can elect to
incorporate in its agreement any of the terms of the
other distributor’s agreement that it wants to
incorporate.
5 See United States v. Apple, 791 F.3d 290, 319
(2d Cir. 2015), citing Blue Cross & Blue Shield
United of Wisconsin v. Marshfield Clinic, 65 F.3d
1406, 141 (7th Cir. 1995).
6 See Steven C. Salop & Fiona Scott Morton,
Developing an Administrable MFN Enforcement
Policy, 27 Antitrust 15, 15 (2013); Jonathan B. Baker
& Judith A. Chevalier, The Competitive
Consequences of Most-Favored-Nation Provisions,
27 Antitrust 20, 21–22 (2013).
7 For example, some means of enforcement may
include ‘‘self-policing’’ by the programmer, an
inquiry initiated by the MVPD, or contractual rights
that permit an MVPD to periodically audit the
programmer.
PO 00000
Frm 00039
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
E:\FR\FM\29FEN1.SGM
29FEN1
asabaliauskas on DSK5VPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
10244
Federal Register / Vol. 81, No. 39 / Monday, February 29, 2016 / Notices
MVPDs in exchange for agreeing to MFN
provisions?
10. Alternative Distribution Method
Provisions. An ADM provision restricts
a programmer’s ability to distribute its
programming via an alternate platform,
often explicitly prohibiting specific nonMVPD distribution methods (such as
online platforms) and often for a
specified period of time (commonly
referred to as a ‘‘window’’) following the
programming’s original airing on a
traditional distribution channel.8 ADMs
may take a variety of less-than-absolute
forms. For example, some provisions
may ban the distribution of content on
a platform that carries fewer than a
prescribed minimum number of
channels. This type of restriction may
have the effect of preventing a
programmer from taking advantage of a
desired distribution opportunity, such
as OTT distribution. According to some
industry observers, in some cases, a
programmer that wishes to distribute its
content online faces the risk that
MVPDs will refuse to carry its network.
Independent video programmers argue
that limitations on the sharing or
licensing of an independent network’s
content online reduce the network’s
ability to advertise and promote its
content, as well as to share original
reporting and newsgathering with other
outlets. On the other hand, an ADM
provision might encourage an MVPD to
provide an independent programmer
with distribution that it otherwise
would not receive if it decided to also
make its content available on alternative
platforms.
11. We seek comment on the
prevalence and scope of ADMs in
contracts for carriage of non-broadcast
video programming as well as the costs
and benefits associated with such
provisions. We request input on the
extent to which ADM provisions vary,
the consideration offered in exchange
for such provisions, and the ways in
which distributors enforce ADM
provisions. Are ADM provisions
included in carriage contracts between
independent programmers and OTT
distributors, or are they included only
in MVPD carriage contracts? Are ADM
provisions included only in carriage
contracts involving independent
programmers or are they included in
contracts involving vertically integrated
programmers as well? Do both cable and
non-cable MVPDs require such
provisions? Are there specific
provisions or means of enforcement of
ADM provisions that are more common
8A
traditional distribution channel typically
offers linear programming–programming
prescheduled by the programming provider.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
19:23 Feb 26, 2016
Jkt 238001
to independent programmers than
others, or that have a different effect on
independent programmers? Is there an
industry standard for the windowing
restrictions included in ADM
provisions? Are certain window
requirements more harmful to
independent programmers than others,
and if so, how prevalent are such
requirements? In addition to carriage, do
independent programmers receive any
consideration, economic or noneconomic, from MVPDs in exchange for
agreeing to ADM provisions? By
providing MVPDs with incentives to
carry new or under-exposed content,
can ADM provisions actually enable
independent programmers to gain
MVPD carriage and thereby increase the
exposure of their programming? Are
there other benefits associated with
these provisions?
12. We also seek comment on the
impact of MFN and ADM provisions on
the video marketplace and on the
availability of independent
programming. Do such provisions
thwart competition, diversity, or
innovation? Or do they increase MVPD’s
willingness to contract with
independent programmers? Do these
types of provisions reflect a proper
balance between an MVPD’s legitimate
interest in being the exclusive
distributor of programming content for a
set period of time and a programmer’s
legitimate interest in providing its
programming to diverse distributors and
platforms? We seek comment on
whether MFN and ADM provisions may
be used to limit the ability of
independent programmers to
experiment with new or unique
distribution models or to tailor deals
with smaller MVPDs or online
distributors. In particular, how might
MFNs or ADMs limit the ability of a
programmer to license or distribute its
programming over-the-top or via its own
platforms, including as part of a directto-consumer Web site or application
that offers linear or on-demand content?
Are there specific types of provisions
(e.g., unconditional MFNs or ADMs
restricting paid distribution) that are
aimed more at restricting new means of
distribution than at facilitating efficient
negotiations or protecting an MVPD’s
investment in programming? Are there
specific types of MFN or ADM
provisions that are pro-competitive and
enhance independent programmers’
ability to gain MVPD carriage?
13. Other Contractual Provisions and
OTT Carriage. We also seek comment
on whether there are other types of
contractual provisions besides MFN and
ADM provisions that are used today that
impact, in a negative or positive way,
PO 00000
Frm 00040
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
the ability of independent programmers
to distribute their programming. Are
there circumstances under which these
limits actually end up enabling MVPD
distribution of program content that
might not otherwise be carried? Aside
from contractual issues, are there are
other aspects of MVPD carriage that are
preventing the creation and distribution
of diverse, independent programming?
Ensuring diverse and novel
programming requires a viable,
profitable business model, for both
MVPDs and programmers. Is it possible
to sustain a business model based upon
carriage by a collection of small MVPDs,
or is it necessary to obtain carriage by
a larger MVPD in order to attract
carriage by additional MVPDs? Is there
a threshold level of MVPD carriage that
is necessary to sustain a viable business
model?
14. In addition, we request input on
the costs and benefits to independent
programmers of forgoing MVPD carriage
to pursue OTT carriage. While OTT
distribution has lower barriers to entry,
it is still a nascent service in some
respects. Is the OTT platform a viable
business model? Is it a viable alternative
to MVPD carriage? If not, what must
happen before it can be considered a
viable business model? Does the OTT
platform provide an easier path to
marketplace success? What benefits of
carriage (e.g., level of viewership or
advertising revenue) on OTT platforms
are necessary for an independent
programmer to remain viable? What are
the difficulties new and emerging
programmers face in negotiating for
these benefits? How do the benefits of
carriage on OTT platforms compare
with the benefits of carriage on MVPD
platforms? Do MVPDs offer favorable
carriage terms that OTT platforms are
unable to offer? If so, what are these
terms and to what extent are these terms
necessary to remain viable in today’s
marketplace? Can a successful OTT
experience lead to future MVPD carriage
and/or vice versa? To the extent
possible, we request that commenters
provide examples of independent
programmers that have been able to
launch and grow on OTT platforms.
Despite such launch and growth, are
there additional challenges that
independent programmers face in
gaining carriage and growing their
viewership on OTT platforms? If so,
what are they and what effect do they
have? Are any of these challenges
particular to diverse and niche
programmers?
2. Program Bundling
15. MVPDs claim that some large
media entities with multiple program
E:\FR\FM\29FEN1.SGM
29FEN1
asabaliauskas on DSK5VPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
Federal Register / Vol. 81, No. 39 / Monday, February 29, 2016 / Notices
offerings, including vertically-integrated
programmers, are able to force MVPDs
to carry less desirable content through
bundling arrangements. In particular,
these parties assert that such entities
often leverage their marquee
programming (e.g., premium channels
or regional sports programming) to force
MVPDs to carry additional channels that
have little or no consumer demand.
Some parties maintain that the
proliferation of bundling arrangements
limits programming choices and raises
costs for consumers by forcing MVPDs
to accept less desirable programming
that may displace independent and
diverse programming. Independent
programmers argue that bundling
arrangements drain the resources and
monopolize the channel capacity of
MVPDs to the detriment of independent
programming. MVPDs that desire to cut
costs then may drop independent
programming from their lineups, refuse
to carry new programming, or offer
carriage only on terms less favorable to
independent programmers. Other
independent programmers argue that
forced bundling is merely a pretext used
by MVPDs in order to justify continued
denial of carriage for independent
programming. Along similar lines, some
parties have claimed that programmers
impose an extra charge on MVPDs for
subscriber access to their online
programming and that this has the
potential to drain resources that might
otherwise be devoted to carriage of
independent programming. How
pervasive is this practice?
16. Large programmers have defended
the use of program bundles and refuted
arguments that they have adverse effects
on MVPDs or consumers. They maintain
that, through the bundling of
programming, MVPDs have the option
of obtaining valuable programming at
discounted prices. In this regard, such
programmers contend that these
programming bundles—offered to both
small and large MVPDs—offer
substantially greater value to MVPDs
and consumers than standalone offers.
17. We invite comment on the impact
of bundling practices. To what extent
does bundling constrain MVPDs from
carrying independent programming? Do
smaller MVPDs feel the constraints of
bundling more acutely than large
MVPDs because of their limited capacity
or limited resources? Does bundling
benefit consumers by lowering prices
for content? Are there any instances of
independent programmers being
dropped or not carried at all because of
the constraints placed on MVPD
systems as a result of bundling? To what
extent do bundling practices, together
with capacity constraints, result in
VerDate Sep<11>2014
19:23 Feb 26, 2016
Jkt 238001
independent programmers being
dropped from MVPDs’ channel lineups?
Are capacity constraints as significant as
they were years ago? With technological
changes, will capacity constraints be a
less significant issue in the future?
18. Recently, the marketplace has
trended away from large MVPD bundles.
Some MVPDs have begun offering
smaller programming packages, and
programmers have launched a number
`
of online a la carte and on-demand
program offerings. We seek comment on
what effect, if any, these trends have
had on independent programmers.
Some MVPDs have argued that these
trends threaten independent
programmers. They assert, among other
things, that these trends undermine the
economics of large MVPD bundles that
have enabled MVPDs to carry
independent programmers offering
diverse and niche programming to
consumers. Is there evidence to support
the claims that marketplace trends
`
toward smaller bundles and a la carte or
on-demand offerings adversely impact
independent programmers or reduce
consumer choice in programming?
Alternatively, is there any evidence
suggesting that these trends may
provide benefits to independent
programmers?
C. Other Marketplace Obstacles
19. In a number of proceedings,
independent programmers have cited
other obstacles in their efforts to secure
carriage by certain MVPDs or OTT
providers. According to some
programmers, for example, some
MVPDs, rather than refusing carriage
outright to a programmer (which might
spur a complaint), instead will
purposefully fail to respond to carriage
negotiation requests in a timely manner
or fail to acknowledge such requests
entirely. Independent programmers
further claim that when MVPDs do
respond to carriage requests, they in
some cases knowingly put forth
inadequate counter offers. Independent
programmers also claim that some
MVPDs have employed a tactic of
avoiding negotiations until just before
the expiration of existing carriage
agreements, thereby forcing
independent programmers to accept
uncertain, month-to-month carriage
arrangements. We seek comment on
whether these practices are being
employed, and if so, the extent to which
they are being used, as well as examples
that demonstrate the impact of such
practices. To what extent, if at all, do
such practices impede entry by or
successful growth of independent
programmers? Are there other practices
or marketplace issues (e.g., demands by
PO 00000
Frm 00041
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
10245
MVPDs for an ownership stake in
independent programmers, channel
placement, or tiering practices) that may
impede the entry or growth of
independent programmers? Are there
practices that benefit the growth of
independent programmers?
20. We also seek comment on the
extent to which some independent
programmers may have leverage over
some MVPDs. For example, are there
situations in which an independent
programmer may condition any
potential carriage arrangement on
carriage by an MVPD of its suite of
programming on distribution to a very
high percentage of the MVPD’s
customers (i.e., minimum penetration
requirements)? How would such
practices affect the ability of MVPDs to
offer ‘‘skinny’’ bundles that could be
combined with OTT services that could
include more diverse and independent
programming? Similarly, we seek
comment on assertions made by some
MVPDs that certain programmers insist
on tier placement commitments that
compel MVPDs to place entire bundles
in the most popular programming
packages. How do programmers
typically calculate the number of video
subscribers that minimum penetration
requirements are based on?
21. Consumer advocacy groups and
PEG providers contend that MVPDs do
not make PEG programming and
information about PEG programming
adequately available to subscribers. For
example, they argue that some MVPDs
often do not provide in their on-screen
menus or guides basic information
about PEG channels and programs, such
as information about accessibility,
channel names, or program names or
descriptions. They assert that the failure
by MVPDs to provide the same level of
program description information for
PEG channels that they offer for other
programmers discriminates against PEG
providers. In other proceedings, these
parties have advocated that the
Commission mandate a
nondiscriminatory approach that would
require MVPDs to provide PEG
information on their program guides on
the same terms and conditions as other
programmers if a PEG programmer
supplies program-specific information.
We seek comment on MVPDs’ practices
with respect to making PEG
programming information available to
subscribers. To the extent that MVPDs
do not make this information available,
is this for technical reasons, and, if so,
can the technical barriers be
surmounted? Is the Congressionallyimposed prohibition against editorial
control of PEG channels relevant to this
E:\FR\FM\29FEN1.SGM
29FEN1
10246
Federal Register / Vol. 81, No. 39 / Monday, February 29, 2016 / Notices
asabaliauskas on DSK5VPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
issue? 9 What is the source of the
Commission’s authority in this area, if
any?
D. Possible Regulatory Tools for
Addressing Market Obstacles Faced by
Independent Programmers
22. What role, if any, should the
Commission play in addressing any
obstacles that prevent greater access by
consumers to sources of independent
and diverse programming? Are there
other entities—including other agencies,
Congress or private entities—that could
play a role in addressing these
obstacles? Can the marketplace
evolution toward greater competition
and choice among distribution
platforms be expected to ease any
obstacles, or may it exacerbate them in
some respects? Are the Commission’s
existing regulatory tools adequate to
address any obstacles? Are there actions
that we could recommend that others
explore in order to promote
programming diversity? Is there a role
for other federal agencies in this review?
Are there concerns that would be
appropriate to refer to the Department of
Justice and/or the Federal Trade
Commission? 10 We seek comment on
any regulatory or other approaches the
Commission should take to alleviate
obstacles to the distribution of
independent and diverse programming.
23. We also seek comment on the
Commission’s legal authority to
alleviate any obstacles. Specifically, we
seek comment on whether section 257
of the Communications Act of 1934, as
amended (Act), provides the
Commission with authority to impose
regulations aimed at improving
programming diversity. In particular, we
seek comment on section 257(b), which
directs the Commission to promote the
policies and purposes of the Act
favoring diversity of media voices,
vigorous economic competition,
technological advancement, and
promotion of the public interest,
convenience, and necessity.11 We also
request input on whether Section 616(a)
of the Act provides the Commission
with the authority to take action with
respect to program carriage practices
that may have an adverse impact on
independent programmers. Specifically,
we invite comment on section 616(a)’s
mandate that the Commission establish
regulations governing program carriage
agreements and related practices
9 47
U.S.C. 533(e).
note that the Commission acts in a manner
that is both complementary to the work of the
antitrust agencies and supported by their
application of antitrust laws. See generally 47
U.S.C. 152(b).
11 47 U.S.C. 257(b).
10 We
VerDate Sep<11>2014
19:23 Feb 26, 2016
Jkt 238001
between cable operators or other
multichannel video programming
distributors and video programming
vendors.12 What other authority does
the Commission or others have to
alleviate obstacles to the distribution of
independent and diverse programming?
III. Procedural Matters
24. Ex Parte Rules. This is an exempt
proceeding in which ex parte
presentations are permitted (except
during the Sunshine Agenda period)
and need not be disclosed.13
25. Filing Requirements. Pursuant to
Sections 1.415 and 1.419 of the
Commission’s rules, 47 CFR 1.415,
1.419, interested parties may file
comments and reply comments on or
before the dates indicated on the first
page of this document. Comments may
be filed using the Commission’s
Electronic Comment Filing System
(ECFS). See Electronic Filing of
Documents in Rulemaking Proceedings,
63 FR 24121 (1998).
• Electronic Filers: Comments may be
filed electronically using the Internet by
accessing the ECFS: https://
fjallfoss.fcc.gov/ecfs2/.
• Paper Filers: Parties who choose to
file by paper must file an original and
one copy of each filing. If more than one
docket or rulemaking number appears in
the caption of this proceeding, filers
must submit two additional copies for
each additional docket or rulemaking
number.
Filings can be sent by hand or
messenger delivery, by commercial
overnight courier, or by first-class or
overnight U.S. Postal Service mail. All
filings must be addressed to the
Commission’s Secretary, Office of the
Secretary, Federal Communications
Commission.
Æ All hand-delivered or messengerdelivered paper filings for the
Commission’s Secretary must be
delivered to FCC Headquarters at 445
12th St. SW., Room TW–A325,
Washington, DC 20554. The filing hours
are 8:00 a.m. to 7:00 p.m. All hand
deliveries must be held together with
rubber bands or fasteners. Any
envelopes and boxes must be disposed
of before entering the building.
Æ Commercial overnight mail (other
than U.S. Postal Service Express Mail
and Priority Mail) must be sent to 9300
East Hampton Drive, Capitol Heights,
MD 20743.
Æ U.S. Postal Service first-class,
Express, and Priority mail must be
addressed to 445 12th Street SW.,
Washington, DC 20554.
12 47
13 47
PO 00000
U.S.C. 536.
CFR 1.1204(b)(1).
Frm 00042
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
26. Availability of Documents.
Comments, reply comments, and ex
parte submissions will be available for
public inspection during regular
business hours in the FCC Reference
Center, Federal Communications
Commission, 445 12th Street SW., CY–
A257, Washington, DC 20554. These
documents will also be available via
ECFS. Documents will be available
electronically in ASCII, Microsoft Word,
and/or Adobe Acrobat.
27. People with Disabilities. To
request materials in accessible formats
for people with disabilities (Braille,
large print, electronic files, audio
format), send an email to fcc504@fcc.gov
or call the FCC’s Consumer and
Governmental Affairs Bureau at (202)
418–0530 (voice), (202) 418–0432
(TTY).
28. Additional Information. For
additional information on this
proceeding, contact Calisha Myers or
Raelynn Remy of the Policy Division,
Media Bureau, at Calisha.Myers@
fcc.gov, Raelynn.Remy@fcc.gov, or (202)
418–2120.
IV. Ordering Clause
29. Accordingly, IT IS ORDERED that,
pursuant to Sections 1, 4(i), 4(j), 303(r),
and 403 of the Communications Act of
1934, as amended, 47 U.S.C §§ 151,
154(i), 154(j), 303(r), 403, this Notice of
Inquiry IS ADOPTED.
Federal Communications Commission.
Marlene H. Dortch,
Secretary.
[FR Doc. 2016–04331 Filed 2–26–16; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6712–01–P
FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS
COMMISSION
Federal Advisory Committee Act;
Communications Security, Reliability,
and Interoperability Council
Federal Communications
Commission.
ACTION: Notice of public meeting.
AGENCY:
In accordance with the
Federal Advisory Committee Act, this
notice advises interested persons that
the Federal Communications
Commission’s (FCC or Commission)
Communications Security, Reliability,
and Interoperability Council (CSRIC) V
will hold its fourth meeting.
DATES: March 16, 2016.
ADDRESSES: Federal Communications
Commission, Room TW–C305
(Commission Meeting Room), 445 12th
Street SW., Washington, DC 20554.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
Jeffery Goldthorp, Designated Federal
SUMMARY:
E:\FR\FM\29FEN1.SGM
29FEN1
Agencies
[Federal Register Volume 81, Number 39 (Monday, February 29, 2016)]
[Notices]
[Pages 10241-10246]
From the Federal Register Online via the Government Publishing Office [www.gpo.gov]
[FR Doc No: 2016-04331]
=======================================================================
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION
[MB Docket No. 16-41; FCC 16-19]
Promoting the Availability of Diverse and Independent Sources of
Video Programming
AGENCY: Federal Communications Commission.
ACTION: Notice of inquiry.
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
SUMMARY: In this document, the Commission seeks comment on the
principal issues that independent video programmers confront in gaining
carriage in the current marketplace and possible actions the Commission
or others might take to address those issues. The goal of this
proceeding is to begin a conversation on the state of independent and
diverse programming, and to assess how the Commission or others could
foster greater consumer choice and enhance diversity in the evolving
video marketplace by
[[Page 10242]]
eliminating or reducing any barriers faced by independent programmers
in reaching viewers. The Commission seeks to explore ways to alleviate
such barriers, as well as its legal authority to do so.
DATES: Comments are due on or before March 30, 2016; reply comments are
due on or before April 19, 2016.
ADDRESSES: You may submit comments, identified by MB Docket No. 16-41,
by any of the following methods:
Federal eRulemaking Portal: https://www.regulations.gov.
Follow the instructions for submitting comments.
Federal Communications Commission's Web site: https://fjallfoss.fcc.gov/ecfs2/. Follow the instructions for submitting
comments.
Mail: Filings can be sent by hand or messenger delivery,
by commercial overnight courier, or by first-class or overnight U.S.
Postal Service mail. All filings must be addressed to the Commission's
Secretary, Office of the Secretary, Federal Communications Commission.
People with Disabilities: Contact the FCC to request
reasonable accommodations (accessible format documents, sign language
interpreters, CART, etc.) by email: FCC504@fcc.gov or phone: (202) 418-
0530 or TTY: (202) 418-0432.
For detailed instructions for submitting comments and additional
information on the rulemaking process, see the SUPPLEMENTARY
INFORMATION section of this document.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: For additional information on this
proceeding, contact Calisha Myers or Raelynn Remy of the Policy
Division, Media Bureau at (202) 418-2120 or Calisha.Myers@fcc.gov;
Raelynn.Remy@fcc.gov.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: This is a summary of the Commission's Notice
of Inquiry, FCC 16-19, adopted and released on February 18, 2016. The
full text is available for public inspection and copying during regular
business hours in the FCC Reference Center, Federal Communications
Commission, 445 12th Street SW., Room CY-A257, Washington, DC 20554.
This document will also be available via ECFS at https://fjallfoss.fcc.gov/ecfs/. Documents will be available electronically in
ASCII, Microsoft Word, and/or Adobe Acrobat. The complete text may be
purchased from the Commission's copy contractor, 445 12th Street SW.,
Room CY-B402, Washington, DC 20554. Alternative formats are available
for people with disabilities (Braille, large print, electronic files,
audio format), by sending an email to fcc504@fcc.gov or calling the
Commission's Consumer and Governmental Affairs Bureau at (202) 418-0530
(voice), (202) 418-0432 (TTY).
Synopsis
I. Introduction
1. Over the last quarter century, we have seen significant changes
in the media landscape that have fundamentally altered the way in which
Americans access and consume video programming. When Congress passed
the 1992 Cable Act, the majority of American households had access to
only one pay television service, and alternatives to that service were
in their incipient stages. By contrast, consumers today can access
video programming over multiple competing platforms, and the dominance
of incumbent pay TV distributors has eroded. However, incumbent
operators retain a very important position in the video programming
marketplace. Although competition among video distributors has grown,
traditional multichannel video programming distributor (MVPD) carriage
is still important for the growth of many emerging programmers. Some
independent video programmers \1\ have expressed concern that certain
carriage practices of cable operators and other MVPDs may limit their
ability to reach viewers.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1\ For purposes of this proceeding, we define an ``independent
video programmer'' or ``independent programmer'' as one that is not
vertically integrated with a MVPD.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
2. A central objective of multichannel video programming regulation
is to foster a diverse, robust, and competitive marketplace for the
delivery of multichannel video programming.\2\ As the agency charged by
statute with implementing this objective, we seek to start a fact-
finding exercise on the current state of programming diversity. Through
this NOI, we seek comment on the principal issues that independent
video programmers confront in gaining carriage in the current
marketplace and possible actions the Commission or others might take to
address those issues. Our goal in this proceeding is to begin a
conversation on the state of independent and diverse programming, and
to assess how the Commission or others could foster greater consumer
choice and enhance diversity in the evolving video marketplace by
eliminating or reducing any barriers faced by independent programmers
in reaching viewers. For purposes of this NOI, we are particularly
interested in starting a dialogue on barriers experienced by all types
of independent programmers, including small programmers and new
entrants. We seek to explore ways that the Commission can alleviate
such barriers, as well as its legal authority to do so. Similar to the
Commission's exploratory efforts in other proceedings, we also seek to
be better informed to make any potential recommendations to other
agencies, Congress, or the private sector, if we find that solutions to
barriers exist that are beyond the authority of this agency. We also
are interested in addressing challenges faced by a specific type of
independent programmer--namely, public, educational, and governmental
(PEG) channels --with respect to MVPD carriage.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\2\ See, e.g., Telecommunications Act of 1996, Pub L. 104-104,
Sec. 257(b), 110 Stat. 56, 77, (codified at 47 U.S.C. 257(b)); 47
U.S.C. 521; 47 U.S.C. 532(a); 47 U.S.C. 533(f)(2). See also 47
U.S.C. 521(a)(4), (b)(1) through (5); H.R. No. 102-862, at 2, 1992
U.S.C.C.A.N. 1231, 1232.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
II. Discussion
A. State of the Marketplace for Independent Programming
3. The Commission seeks information on the current state of the
marketplace for independent programming and the availability of such
programming to consumers. Has the number of independent programmers
grown or decreased? Has the diversity of programming available to
consumers expanded or contracted? What percentage of non-broadcast
networks are independent programmers? We also seek input on the manner
in which independent programmers are carried by distributors and
whether the answers to the following questions differ for independent
programmers and vertically integrated programmers. To what extent are
independent programmers carried by traditional MVPDs and to what extent
are they carried by over-the-top (OTT) providers? How many of the
independent networks distributed by MVPDs are also available on OTT
platforms? Is it more difficult for independent programmers to gain
carriage on certain MVPDs than others (e.g., cable vs. non-cable MVPDs,
or smaller vs. larger MVPDs)? Does the size of the MVPD matter? Is
there a disparity in the amount of independent programming on smaller
versus larger MVPDs? Do large MVPDs have market power that has an
effect on the ability of independent programmers to obtain carriage?
Conversely, to what extent does the size of the independent programmer
matter? Do large independent programmers have an easier time getting
carried than smaller ones? Are there characteristics of independent
programmers that enable some to gain MVPD carriage but not
[[Page 10243]]
others? To what extent does the level of competition among MVPDs impact
the bargaining leverage of independent programmers in negotiations for
carriage deals? With regard to the foregoing questions, commenters
should provide examples of and relevant information regarding specific
independent program networks.
B. Principal Marketplace Obstacles Faced by Independent Programmers
4. Independent programmers and others have alleged in various
proceedings that cable operators and other MVPDs engage in program
carriage practices that hamper the ability of programmers with limited
bargaining leverage to obtain distribution of their content. They claim
that these practices deprive consumers of the benefits of competition,
including greater choice and diversity in programming content. We seek
input below on several practices that independent programmers allege
have an adverse impact on them.\3\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\3\ Pursuant to section 103(c) of the STELA Reauthorization Act
of 2014, the Commission recently issued a Notice of Proposed
Rulemaking to review the totality of the circumstances test for
evaluating whether broadcast stations and MVPDs are negotiating for
retransmission consent in good faith. See Implementation of section
103 of the STELA Reauthorization Act of 2014, Totality of the
Circumstances Test, MB Docket No. 15-216, Notice of Proposed
Rulemaking, 80 FR 59706 (2015) (Totality of the Circumstances NPRM).
Some of the issues raised in this NOI regarding negotiations between
MVPDs and programmers in general are similar to issues raised in the
Totality of the Circumstances NPRM. However, we direct parties
wishing to comment on issues relating to retransmission consent
negotiations between broadcasters and MVPDs to file any comments on
those issues in the Totality of the Circumstances NPRM docket.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
1. Insistence on Contract Provisions That Constrain the Ability of
Independent Programmers To Compete
5. Independent programmers and others have asserted that certain
MVPDs often demand that carriage agreements include certain contractual
provisions, such as most favored nation (MFN) and alternative
distribution method (ADM) clauses, that hinder programming competition,
innovation, and diversity.
6. Most Favored Nation Provisions. In general, MFN provisions
entitle the contracting video programming distributor to modify a
programming agreement to incorporate more favorable rates, contract
terms, or conditions that the contracting programmer later agrees to
with another distributor.\4\ These provisions are the result of
contractual agreements between programmers and distributors. MFN
clauses historically were used to protect favorable carriage rates
obtained by MVPDs that brought a large subscriber base to the
programmer, but can be misused to anticompetitive means in some
cases.\5\ Independent programmers claim that some MVPDs increasingly
have insisted on MFN treatment without regard to the concessions or
commitments made by the programmer to secure those terms from another
MVPD and without requiring the MVPD to deliver commensurate value to
the programmer.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\4\ MFN rights can be conditional or unconditional. A
conditional MFN provision entitles a distributor to certain
contractual rights that the programmer has granted to another
distributor, as long as the distributor also accepts equivalent or
related terms and conditions contained in that other distributor's
agreement. An unconditional MFN provision, by contrast, contains no
such requirement that the distributor entitled to MFN rights accept
equivalent or related terms and conditions; it can elect to
incorporate in its agreement any of the terms of the other
distributor's agreement that it wants to incorporate.
\5\ See United States v. Apple, 791 F.3d 290, 319 (2d Cir.
2015), citing Blue Cross & Blue Shield United of Wisconsin v.
Marshfield Clinic, 65 F.3d 1406, 141 (7th Cir. 1995).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
7. Some parties claim that MVPDs' insistence on MFN provisions
precludes an independent programmer from making unique or innovative
arrangements designed to achieve initial carriage of new programming,
because those same unique terms could then be required to be extended
to all MVPDs. They further argue that, given the proliferation of MFN
provisions, an independent programmer that achieves some carriage is
likely to have numerous MFN obligations, and that this can initiate a
``domino effect'' when a single term in an agreement with one MVPD or
OTT service triggers the MFN obligations in a programmer's agreements
with other MVPDs. In particular, the prospect of having to make the
same concessions to all of the MVPDs with which an independent
programmer has MFN obligations may impede the ability of independent
programmers to negotiate carriage agreements with new-entrant
distributors that have smaller subscriber bases, such as new OTT
distributors. As a result, programmers and some advocacy groups claim,
some MVPDs are able to demand MFN concessions from independent
programmers that make OTT distribution economically infeasible, which
deters independent programmers from developing new and innovative types
of video programming, inhibits new distribution models, and limits the
diversity of programming available to consumers. On the other hand,
some antitrust analyses have noted that in some situations MFN
provisions may yield benefits, such as lower prices, reduced
transaction costs, or the development of new products.\6\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\6\ See Steven C. Salop & Fiona Scott Morton, Developing an
Administrable MFN Enforcement Policy, 27 Antitrust 15, 15 (2013);
Jonathan B. Baker & Judith A. Chevalier, The Competitive
Consequences of Most-Favored-Nation Provisions, 27 Antitrust 20, 21-
22 (2013).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
8. We seek comment on the prevalence and scope of MFNs today in
contracts for carriage of non-broadcast video programming. Are MFN
provisions included in carriage contracts between independent
programmers and OTT distributors, or do they tend to be included only
in MVPD carriage contracts? Are MFN provisions more often included in
carriage contracts involving independent programmers than those
involving vertically integrated programmers? Does the size of the MVPD
or independent programmer affect whether MFN provisions are included in
carriage contracts? Do MFN provisions in carriage agreements between
MVPDs and independent programmers cover the terms of both other MVPD
agreements and OTT agreements? If so, how often do such MFN provisions
extend to OTT agreements? Do both cable and non-cable MVPDs require MFN
provisions? Do MFN provisions allow MVPDs to ``cherry pick,'' i.e., to
take advantage of the lower price available in a separate carriage
agreement without a reciprocal obligation? If so, how often? Will MVPDs
accept some reciprocal obligations while refusing other reciprocal
obligations?
9. We also seek comment on the costs and benefits of these
provisions. Are there specific types of MFN provisions that
particularly hinder the creation and distribution of new or niche
programming? If so, how do those provisions have this effect? How do
distributors enforce MFN provisions? Are there specific means of
enforcement that are more common or more onerous to independent
programmers than others? \7\ What benefits are associated with MFN
provisions, and are there contexts in which the benefits outweigh any
harmful effects of such provisions? Do MFNs result in lower prices for
consumers? Do they enhance the likelihood that a start-up independent
programmer will be able to gain carriage on MVPDs? Do they reduce
transaction costs between MVPDs and independent programmers? Do
independent programmers receive any consideration, economic or non-
economic, from
[[Page 10244]]
MVPDs in exchange for agreeing to MFN provisions?
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\7\ For example, some means of enforcement may include ``self-
policing'' by the programmer, an inquiry initiated by the MVPD, or
contractual rights that permit an MVPD to periodically audit the
programmer.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
10. Alternative Distribution Method Provisions. An ADM provision
restricts a programmer's ability to distribute its programming via an
alternate platform, often explicitly prohibiting specific non-MVPD
distribution methods (such as online platforms) and often for a
specified period of time (commonly referred to as a ``window'')
following the programming's original airing on a traditional
distribution channel.\8\ ADMs may take a variety of less-than-absolute
forms. For example, some provisions may ban the distribution of content
on a platform that carries fewer than a prescribed minimum number of
channels. This type of restriction may have the effect of preventing a
programmer from taking advantage of a desired distribution opportunity,
such as OTT distribution. According to some industry observers, in some
cases, a programmer that wishes to distribute its content online faces
the risk that MVPDs will refuse to carry its network. Independent video
programmers argue that limitations on the sharing or licensing of an
independent network's content online reduce the network's ability to
advertise and promote its content, as well as to share original
reporting and newsgathering with other outlets. On the other hand, an
ADM provision might encourage an MVPD to provide an independent
programmer with distribution that it otherwise would not receive if it
decided to also make its content available on alternative platforms.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\8\ A traditional distribution channel typically offers linear
programming-programming prescheduled by the programming provider.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
11. We seek comment on the prevalence and scope of ADMs in
contracts for carriage of non-broadcast video programming as well as
the costs and benefits associated with such provisions. We request
input on the extent to which ADM provisions vary, the consideration
offered in exchange for such provisions, and the ways in which
distributors enforce ADM provisions. Are ADM provisions included in
carriage contracts between independent programmers and OTT
distributors, or are they included only in MVPD carriage contracts? Are
ADM provisions included only in carriage contracts involving
independent programmers or are they included in contracts involving
vertically integrated programmers as well? Do both cable and non-cable
MVPDs require such provisions? Are there specific provisions or means
of enforcement of ADM provisions that are more common to independent
programmers than others, or that have a different effect on independent
programmers? Is there an industry standard for the windowing
restrictions included in ADM provisions? Are certain window
requirements more harmful to independent programmers than others, and
if so, how prevalent are such requirements? In addition to carriage, do
independent programmers receive any consideration, economic or non-
economic, from MVPDs in exchange for agreeing to ADM provisions? By
providing MVPDs with incentives to carry new or under-exposed content,
can ADM provisions actually enable independent programmers to gain MVPD
carriage and thereby increase the exposure of their programming? Are
there other benefits associated with these provisions?
12. We also seek comment on the impact of MFN and ADM provisions on
the video marketplace and on the availability of independent
programming. Do such provisions thwart competition, diversity, or
innovation? Or do they increase MVPD's willingness to contract with
independent programmers? Do these types of provisions reflect a proper
balance between an MVPD's legitimate interest in being the exclusive
distributor of programming content for a set period of time and a
programmer's legitimate interest in providing its programming to
diverse distributors and platforms? We seek comment on whether MFN and
ADM provisions may be used to limit the ability of independent
programmers to experiment with new or unique distribution models or to
tailor deals with smaller MVPDs or online distributors. In particular,
how might MFNs or ADMs limit the ability of a programmer to license or
distribute its programming over-the-top or via its own platforms,
including as part of a direct-to-consumer Web site or application that
offers linear or on-demand content? Are there specific types of
provisions (e.g., unconditional MFNs or ADMs restricting paid
distribution) that are aimed more at restricting new means of
distribution than at facilitating efficient negotiations or protecting
an MVPD's investment in programming? Are there specific types of MFN or
ADM provisions that are pro-competitive and enhance independent
programmers' ability to gain MVPD carriage?
13. Other Contractual Provisions and OTT Carriage. We also seek
comment on whether there are other types of contractual provisions
besides MFN and ADM provisions that are used today that impact, in a
negative or positive way, the ability of independent programmers to
distribute their programming. Are there circumstances under which these
limits actually end up enabling MVPD distribution of program content
that might not otherwise be carried? Aside from contractual issues, are
there are other aspects of MVPD carriage that are preventing the
creation and distribution of diverse, independent programming? Ensuring
diverse and novel programming requires a viable, profitable business
model, for both MVPDs and programmers. Is it possible to sustain a
business model based upon carriage by a collection of small MVPDs, or
is it necessary to obtain carriage by a larger MVPD in order to attract
carriage by additional MVPDs? Is there a threshold level of MVPD
carriage that is necessary to sustain a viable business model?
14. In addition, we request input on the costs and benefits to
independent programmers of forgoing MVPD carriage to pursue OTT
carriage. While OTT distribution has lower barriers to entry, it is
still a nascent service in some respects. Is the OTT platform a viable
business model? Is it a viable alternative to MVPD carriage? If not,
what must happen before it can be considered a viable business model?
Does the OTT platform provide an easier path to marketplace success?
What benefits of carriage (e.g., level of viewership or advertising
revenue) on OTT platforms are necessary for an independent programmer
to remain viable? What are the difficulties new and emerging
programmers face in negotiating for these benefits? How do the benefits
of carriage on OTT platforms compare with the benefits of carriage on
MVPD platforms? Do MVPDs offer favorable carriage terms that OTT
platforms are unable to offer? If so, what are these terms and to what
extent are these terms necessary to remain viable in today's
marketplace? Can a successful OTT experience lead to future MVPD
carriage and/or vice versa? To the extent possible, we request that
commenters provide examples of independent programmers that have been
able to launch and grow on OTT platforms. Despite such launch and
growth, are there additional challenges that independent programmers
face in gaining carriage and growing their viewership on OTT platforms?
If so, what are they and what effect do they have? Are any of these
challenges particular to diverse and niche programmers?
2. Program Bundling
15. MVPDs claim that some large media entities with multiple
program
[[Page 10245]]
offerings, including vertically-integrated programmers, are able to
force MVPDs to carry less desirable content through bundling
arrangements. In particular, these parties assert that such entities
often leverage their marquee programming (e.g., premium channels or
regional sports programming) to force MVPDs to carry additional
channels that have little or no consumer demand. Some parties maintain
that the proliferation of bundling arrangements limits programming
choices and raises costs for consumers by forcing MVPDs to accept less
desirable programming that may displace independent and diverse
programming. Independent programmers argue that bundling arrangements
drain the resources and monopolize the channel capacity of MVPDs to the
detriment of independent programming. MVPDs that desire to cut costs
then may drop independent programming from their lineups, refuse to
carry new programming, or offer carriage only on terms less favorable
to independent programmers. Other independent programmers argue that
forced bundling is merely a pretext used by MVPDs in order to justify
continued denial of carriage for independent programming. Along similar
lines, some parties have claimed that programmers impose an extra
charge on MVPDs for subscriber access to their online programming and
that this has the potential to drain resources that might otherwise be
devoted to carriage of independent programming. How pervasive is this
practice?
16. Large programmers have defended the use of program bundles and
refuted arguments that they have adverse effects on MVPDs or consumers.
They maintain that, through the bundling of programming, MVPDs have the
option of obtaining valuable programming at discounted prices. In this
regard, such programmers contend that these programming bundles--
offered to both small and large MVPDs--offer substantially greater
value to MVPDs and consumers than standalone offers.
17. We invite comment on the impact of bundling practices. To what
extent does bundling constrain MVPDs from carrying independent
programming? Do smaller MVPDs feel the constraints of bundling more
acutely than large MVPDs because of their limited capacity or limited
resources? Does bundling benefit consumers by lowering prices for
content? Are there any instances of independent programmers being
dropped or not carried at all because of the constraints placed on MVPD
systems as a result of bundling? To what extent do bundling practices,
together with capacity constraints, result in independent programmers
being dropped from MVPDs' channel lineups? Are capacity constraints as
significant as they were years ago? With technological changes, will
capacity constraints be a less significant issue in the future?
18. Recently, the marketplace has trended away from large MVPD
bundles. Some MVPDs have begun offering smaller programming packages,
and programmers have launched a number of online [agrave] la carte and
on-demand program offerings. We seek comment on what effect, if any,
these trends have had on independent programmers. Some MVPDs have
argued that these trends threaten independent programmers. They assert,
among other things, that these trends undermine the economics of large
MVPD bundles that have enabled MVPDs to carry independent programmers
offering diverse and niche programming to consumers. Is there evidence
to support the claims that marketplace trends toward smaller bundles
and [agrave] la carte or on-demand offerings adversely impact
independent programmers or reduce consumer choice in programming?
Alternatively, is there any evidence suggesting that these trends may
provide benefits to independent programmers?
C. Other Marketplace Obstacles
19. In a number of proceedings, independent programmers have cited
other obstacles in their efforts to secure carriage by certain MVPDs or
OTT providers. According to some programmers, for example, some MVPDs,
rather than refusing carriage outright to a programmer (which might
spur a complaint), instead will purposefully fail to respond to
carriage negotiation requests in a timely manner or fail to acknowledge
such requests entirely. Independent programmers further claim that when
MVPDs do respond to carriage requests, they in some cases knowingly put
forth inadequate counter offers. Independent programmers also claim
that some MVPDs have employed a tactic of avoiding negotiations until
just before the expiration of existing carriage agreements, thereby
forcing independent programmers to accept uncertain, month-to-month
carriage arrangements. We seek comment on whether these practices are
being employed, and if so, the extent to which they are being used, as
well as examples that demonstrate the impact of such practices. To what
extent, if at all, do such practices impede entry by or successful
growth of independent programmers? Are there other practices or
marketplace issues (e.g., demands by MVPDs for an ownership stake in
independent programmers, channel placement, or tiering practices) that
may impede the entry or growth of independent programmers? Are there
practices that benefit the growth of independent programmers?
20. We also seek comment on the extent to which some independent
programmers may have leverage over some MVPDs. For example, are there
situations in which an independent programmer may condition any
potential carriage arrangement on carriage by an MVPD of its suite of
programming on distribution to a very high percentage of the MVPD's
customers (i.e., minimum penetration requirements)? How would such
practices affect the ability of MVPDs to offer ``skinny'' bundles that
could be combined with OTT services that could include more diverse and
independent programming? Similarly, we seek comment on assertions made
by some MVPDs that certain programmers insist on tier placement
commitments that compel MVPDs to place entire bundles in the most
popular programming packages. How do programmers typically calculate
the number of video subscribers that minimum penetration requirements
are based on?
21. Consumer advocacy groups and PEG providers contend that MVPDs
do not make PEG programming and information about PEG programming
adequately available to subscribers. For example, they argue that some
MVPDs often do not provide in their on-screen menus or guides basic
information about PEG channels and programs, such as information about
accessibility, channel names, or program names or descriptions. They
assert that the failure by MVPDs to provide the same level of program
description information for PEG channels that they offer for other
programmers discriminates against PEG providers. In other proceedings,
these parties have advocated that the Commission mandate a
nondiscriminatory approach that would require MVPDs to provide PEG
information on their program guides on the same terms and conditions as
other programmers if a PEG programmer supplies program-specific
information. We seek comment on MVPDs' practices with respect to making
PEG programming information available to subscribers. To the extent
that MVPDs do not make this information available, is this for
technical reasons, and, if so, can the technical barriers be
surmounted? Is the Congressionally-imposed prohibition against
editorial control of PEG channels relevant to this
[[Page 10246]]
issue? \9\ What is the source of the Commission's authority in this
area, if any?
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\9\ 47 U.S.C. 533(e).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
D. Possible Regulatory Tools for Addressing Market Obstacles Faced by
Independent Programmers
22. What role, if any, should the Commission play in addressing any
obstacles that prevent greater access by consumers to sources of
independent and diverse programming? Are there other entities--
including other agencies, Congress or private entities--that could play
a role in addressing these obstacles? Can the marketplace evolution
toward greater competition and choice among distribution platforms be
expected to ease any obstacles, or may it exacerbate them in some
respects? Are the Commission's existing regulatory tools adequate to
address any obstacles? Are there actions that we could recommend that
others explore in order to promote programming diversity? Is there a
role for other federal agencies in this review? Are there concerns that
would be appropriate to refer to the Department of Justice and/or the
Federal Trade Commission? \10\ We seek comment on any regulatory or
other approaches the Commission should take to alleviate obstacles to
the distribution of independent and diverse programming.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\10\ We note that the Commission acts in a manner that is both
complementary to the work of the antitrust agencies and supported by
their application of antitrust laws. See generally 47 U.S.C. 152(b).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
23. We also seek comment on the Commission's legal authority to
alleviate any obstacles. Specifically, we seek comment on whether
section 257 of the Communications Act of 1934, as amended (Act),
provides the Commission with authority to impose regulations aimed at
improving programming diversity. In particular, we seek comment on
section 257(b), which directs the Commission to promote the policies
and purposes of the Act favoring diversity of media voices, vigorous
economic competition, technological advancement, and promotion of the
public interest, convenience, and necessity.\11\ We also request input
on whether Section 616(a) of the Act provides the Commission with the
authority to take action with respect to program carriage practices
that may have an adverse impact on independent programmers.
Specifically, we invite comment on section 616(a)'s mandate that the
Commission establish regulations governing program carriage agreements
and related practices between cable operators or other multichannel
video programming distributors and video programming vendors.\12\ What
other authority does the Commission or others have to alleviate
obstacles to the distribution of independent and diverse programming?
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\11\ 47 U.S.C. 257(b).
\12\ 47 U.S.C. 536.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
III. Procedural Matters
24. Ex Parte Rules. This is an exempt proceeding in which ex parte
presentations are permitted (except during the Sunshine Agenda period)
and need not be disclosed.\13\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\13\ 47 CFR 1.1204(b)(1).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
25. Filing Requirements. Pursuant to Sections 1.415 and 1.419 of
the Commission's rules, 47 CFR 1.415, 1.419, interested parties may
file comments and reply comments on or before the dates indicated on
the first page of this document. Comments may be filed using the
Commission's Electronic Comment Filing System (ECFS). See Electronic
Filing of Documents in Rulemaking Proceedings, 63 FR 24121 (1998).
Electronic Filers: Comments may be filed electronically
using the Internet by accessing the ECFS: https://fjallfoss.fcc.gov/ecfs2/.
Paper Filers: Parties who choose to file by paper must
file an original and one copy of each filing. If more than one docket
or rulemaking number appears in the caption of this proceeding, filers
must submit two additional copies for each additional docket or
rulemaking number.
Filings can be sent by hand or messenger delivery, by commercial
overnight courier, or by first-class or overnight U.S. Postal Service
mail. All filings must be addressed to the Commission's Secretary,
Office of the Secretary, Federal Communications Commission.
[cir] All hand-delivered or messenger-delivered paper filings for
the Commission's Secretary must be delivered to FCC Headquarters at 445
12th St. SW., Room TW-A325, Washington, DC 20554. The filing hours are
8:00 a.m. to 7:00 p.m. All hand deliveries must be held together with
rubber bands or fasteners. Any envelopes and boxes must be disposed of
before entering the building.
[cir] Commercial overnight mail (other than U.S. Postal Service
Express Mail and Priority Mail) must be sent to 9300 East Hampton
Drive, Capitol Heights, MD 20743.
[cir] U.S. Postal Service first-class, Express, and Priority mail
must be addressed to 445 12th Street SW., Washington, DC 20554.
26. Availability of Documents. Comments, reply comments, and ex
parte submissions will be available for public inspection during
regular business hours in the FCC Reference Center, Federal
Communications Commission, 445 12th Street SW., CY-A257, Washington, DC
20554. These documents will also be available via ECFS. Documents will
be available electronically in ASCII, Microsoft Word, and/or Adobe
Acrobat.
27. People with Disabilities. To request materials in accessible
formats for people with disabilities (Braille, large print, electronic
files, audio format), send an email to fcc504@fcc.gov or call the FCC's
Consumer and Governmental Affairs Bureau at (202) 418-0530 (voice),
(202) 418-0432 (TTY).
28. Additional Information. For additional information on this
proceeding, contact Calisha Myers or Raelynn Remy of the Policy
Division, Media Bureau, at Calisha.Myers@fcc.gov, Raelynn.Remy@fcc.gov,
or (202) 418-2120.
IV. Ordering Clause
29. Accordingly, IT IS ORDERED that, pursuant to Sections 1, 4(i),
4(j), 303(r), and 403 of the Communications Act of 1934, as amended, 47
U.S.C Sec. Sec. 151, 154(i), 154(j), 303(r), 403, this Notice of
Inquiry IS ADOPTED.
Federal Communications Commission.
Marlene H. Dortch,
Secretary.
[FR Doc. 2016-04331 Filed 2-26-16; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6712-01-P