Rates for Interstate Inmate Calling Services, 79135-79180 [2015-31252]
Download as PDF
Vol. 80
Friday,
No. 243
December 18, 2015
Part II
Federal Communications Commission
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES2
47 CFR Part 64
Rates for Interstate Inmate Calling Services; Final Rule
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:49 Dec 17, 2015
Jkt 238001
PO 00000
Frm 00001
Fmt 4717
Sfmt 4717
E:\FR\FM\18DER2.SGM
18DER2
79136
Federal Register / Vol. 80, No. 243 / Friday, December 18, 2015 / Rules and Regulations
FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS
COMMISSION
47 CFR Part 64
[WC Docket No. 12–375; FCC 15–136]
Rates for Interstate Inmate Calling
Services
Federal Communications
Commission.
ACTION: Final rule.
AGENCY:
In this document, the Federal
Communications Commission
(Commission) adopts comprehensive
reforms of Inmate Calling Services,
regardless of the technology used to
provide service, to ensure just
reasonable and fair rates as mandated by
the Communications Act.
DATES: The rules in this document will
become effective March 17, 2016, and
the Compliance Date for this Second
Report and Order will be January 19,
2016.
SUMMARY:
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
Lynne Engledow, Wireline Competition
Bureau, Pricing Policy Division at (202)
418–1540 or at Lynne.Engledow@
fcc.gov.
This is a
summary of the Commission’s Second
Report and Order, WC Docket 12–375,
released November 5, 2015. The full text
of this document may be downloaded at
the following Internet Address: https://
transition.fcc.gov/Daily_Releases/Daily_
Business/2015/db1105/FCC-15136A1.pdf. To request alternative
formats for persons with disabilities
(e.g. accessible format documents, sign
language, interpreters, CARTS, etc.)
send an email to fcc504@fcc.gov or call
the Commission’s Consumer and
Governmental Affairs Bureau at (202)
418–0530 or (202) 418–0432 (TTY).
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES2
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION:
I. Introduction
1. Twelve years have passed since
Martha Wright of Washington, DC
petitioned this Commission for relief
from exorbitant phone rates charged by
inmate calling service (ICS) providers,
so that she might afford telephone
contact with her incarcerated grandson.
For families, friends, clergy, and
attorneys to the over 2 million
Americans behind bars and 2.7 million
children who have at least one parent
behind bars, maintaining phone contact
has been made extremely difficult due
to prohibitively high charges on those
calls. Family members report paying
egregious amounts, adding up to
hundreds of dollars each month, just to
stay connected to incarcerated spouses,
parents and children. For over a decade,
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:49 Dec 17, 2015
Jkt 238001
they have pleaded with this agency for
help fighting these excessive and
unaffordable phone charges.
2. In the Report and Order, we grant
relief, answer the call of those millions
of citizens seeking ICS reform, and
adopt comprehensive reform of
interstate and intrastate ICS calls to
ensure just, reasonable and fair ICS rates
as mandated by the Act. (Interstate
communication ‘‘means communication
or transmission (A) from any State,
Territory, or possession of the United
States (other than the Canal Zone), or
the District of Columbia, to any State,
Territory, or possession of the United
States (other than the Canal Zone), or
the District of Columbia. Consistent
with our authority under the
Communications Act, this Order applies
to all states and U.S. territories
including Puerto Rico, Guam, and the
U.S. Virgin Islands.) We follow these
reforms with a Further Notice that
recognizes there is more work yet to be
done. While the Commission prefers to
rely on competition and market forces to
discipline prices, there is little dispute
that the ICS market is a prime example
of market failure. Market forces often
lead to more competition, lower prices,
and better services. Unfortunately, the
ICS market, by contrast, is characterized
by increasing rates, with no competitive
pressures to reduce rates. With respect
to the consumers who pay the bills, ICS
providers operate as unchecked
monopolists. The record indicates that,
absent regulatory intervention, ICS rates
and associated ancillary fees likely will
continue to rise. After the adoption of
interim interstate rate caps in 2013,
there was hope that states would take a
more active role in reforming intrastate
ICS rates and ancillary fees. While this
has occurred in a handful of states, such
as Alabama, Minnesota, New Jersey, and
Ohio, the unfortunate reality is that
many states have not tackled reform and
intrastate ICS rates have continued to
increase since the 2013 Order. 78 FR
67956, Nov. 13, 2013.
3. Given this market failure, the
Commission has a duty to act to fulfill
our statutory mandate of ensuring that
ICS rates are just, reasonable, and fair.
Ensuring that rates comply with the
statute also has several positive public
interest benefits. Studies have shown
that family contact during incarceration
reduces recidivism and allows inmates
to be more present parents for the 2.7
million children who suffer when an
incarcerated parent cannot afford to
keep in touch. One commenter tells us
that ‘‘[m]y family paid outrageous
amounts, between $300 and $400 a
month for the 10 months while I was
incarcerated in the state of MD. Their
PO 00000
Frm 00002
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
savings were drained just so they could
correspond with their only daughter
who was pregnant with their first
grandchild at the time.’’ One mother
writes: ‘‘I pay 40 dollars a week for
calls. I can’t afford them but it puts a
smile on my kid’s face;’’ another writes
that her family has, at times, gone
without food in order to pay these
phone charges, ‘‘so we don’t grow apart
and so my kids feel like they still have
a father.’’ These 2.7 million children are
already coping with the anxiety of
having an incarcerated parent, and often
suffer additional economic and personal
hardships that hinder their performance
in school. By charging inmates
exorbitant phone rates, ICS providers
prevent incarcerated parents from
maintaining a presence in their
children’s lives through regular phone
contact. The testimony of a father in St.
Cloud, Minnesota underscores the need
for our efforts: ‘‘I want to be able to raise
my child even if it’s over the phone for
the time being. I would love to be in her
life as much as possible, but it’s hard to
do so when the phone [price] is steadily
climbing higher and higher. I know I’m
paying my debt to society for my crime,
but I need to stay in contact with
family.’’
4. Furthermore, inmates given access
to regular phone contact with family are
less likely to return to jail or prison. A
2014 report by the Department of Justice
found that a staggering 75 percent of
individuals released from prison were
rearrested within five years. Of the
inmates who do find success and
reintegrate after release, many credit
phone contact and family support
during their incarceration. As one
former inmate writes, ‘‘The phone was
my life line to that family and they got
me through it intact. I thank God that
my family was able to afford the phone
calls. What happens to the families that
can’t? We all end up paying for it.’’
Incarceration costs taxpayers an average
of $31,000 per inmate per year. If
telephone contact is made more
affordable, we will help ensure that
former inmates are not sent home as
strangers, which reduces both their
chances of returning to prison or jail
and the attendant burden on society of
housing, feeding, and caring for
additional inmates.
5. Another commenter stresses how
regular phone contact makes prisons
and jails safer spaces for inmates and
officers alike:
I get to see my loved one once in every six
months or so, and he doesn’t get any visitors
apart from me, so calling daily helps him
retain his sanity. I think the connection he’s
given to his family is really important; there
are so many times that he’s called really
E:\FR\FM\18DER2.SGM
18DER2
Federal Register / Vol. 80, No. 243 / Friday, December 18, 2015 / Rules and Regulations
angry at other inmates, saying that he just
wanted to talk so that he can cool down and
not start a fight. If calls are made more
affordable, especially for indigent families, it
may reduce prison violence as well as make
the prisons a safer place for [corrections
officers] to work in.
6. The record indicates that our
interim interstate rate caps increased
call volumes, without compromising
correctional facility security
requirements. Similarly, we expect our
actions in this Order to reduce rates and
increase call volume, while ensuring
that ICS providers receive fair
compensation and a reasonable return.
Some commenters have argued that
lowering ICS rates will compromise
security in correctional facilities and fail
to cover the cost of providing calling
services. Some have even argued the
financial strain from rate regulation
could lead to correctional facilities
banning inmate calls altogether.
However, we find these assertions
unpersuasive and unsupported by the
record and our experience from the
2013 reforms.
7. While the actions taken to date
have been positive in key respects (e.g.,
lower interstate rates and increased
interstate call volume), more remains to
be done. The Commission adopted
interim interstate rate caps, but over 80
percent of calls to and from correctional
facilities are intrastate, and were not
subject to the reforms of the 2013 Order.
Throughout this proceeding, the
Commission has repeatedly called on
states to reform inmate calling within
their jurisdictions, but rates remain
egregiously high in over half the states.
The Commission has the legal authority
to reform the rate structure for all ICS
calls, and herein we determine it is
appropriate and necessary to do so.
8. In addition, we commit to continue
evaluating the impact of these reforms
and to conduct a review in two years to
evaluate the changes in the market and
determine whether further refinements
are appropriate.
II. Executive Summary
9. In the Order, we adopt
comprehensive reform of all aspects of
ICS to correct a market failure, foster
market efficiencies, encourage ongoing
state reforms, and ensure that ICS rates
and charges comply with the
Communications Act. As a threshold
matter, we make clear that the reforms
adopted herein apply to ICS offered in
all correctional facilities, regardless of
the technology used to deliver the
service. Specifically, we take the
following steps, which together form a
comprehensive package of long-overdue
reform to inmate calling services:
• Adopt tiered debit and prepaid rate
caps that apply to all interstate and
intrastate ICS, as well as a tiered rate
cap for collect calling (which, after two
years, will phase down to the rate caps
adopted for prepaid and debit calls);
• Address payments to correctional
institutions by excluding site
commission costs from our rate caps (we
otherwise discourage, but do not
prohibit, ICS providers from sharing
their profits and paying site
commissions to facilities);
• Limit and cap ancillary service
charges and address the potential for
loopholes and gaming, including thirdparty services, thus addressing a
disturbing trend in which ancillary
service charges increased exponentially
and unfairly, to the detriment of inmates
and their families and in contravention
of the statute;
• Prohibit ICS prepaid calling
account funding minimums and
establish an ICS prepaid calling account
funding maximum limit;
• Establish a periodic review of ICS
reforms, recognizing that further
refinements may be appropriate as the
marketplace evolves—thus
complementing the Further Notice we
initiate today (described in more detail
below);
• Make clear that the rate caps and
reforms we adopt today operate as a
ceiling in states that have not enacted
79137
reforms with equal or lower caps on
rates and ancillary fees and that we will
preempt state laws that are inconsistent
with the federal framework;
• Take measures to address ongoing
concerns with access to ICS by inmates
and their families with communications
disabilities, including requiring that the
per-minute rates charged for TTY-toTTY calls be no more than 25 percent
of the rates the providers charge for
traditional inmate calling services and
that no provider shall levy or collect any
charge or fee for TRS-to-voice or voiceto-TTY calls;
• Adopt a transition period for rate
caps and ancillary service charge
reforms of March 17, 2016 for ICS
provided in prisons and June 20, 2016
for ICS provided in jails to enable
providers time to adjust contracts if
necessary, given that the reforms
adopted herein constitute regulatory
changes and thus may trigger change-inlaw provisions in existing ICS contracts;
• Take measures to prevent possible
gaming during the transition to the new
rules adopted herein;
• Require annual reporting and
certification by ICS providers, to allow
the Commission to ensure compliance
and enable monitoring of developments,
and require the providers to be
transparent with regard to disclosure of
their rates and policies;
• Confirm that section 276 of the Act
is technology neutral and thus any
service—regardless of name—that meets
the definitional criteria for ‘‘inmate
calling services’’ is subject to our rules,
including the reforms adopted today;
and
• Make clear that ICS providers may
seek waivers if they are unable to
receive fair compensation or request
that the Commission preempt
inconsistent state laws, and encourage
the Wireline Competition Bureau to
resolve such waivers within 90 days of
submission of complete information.
We adopt the following rate caps.
TABLE ONE
Debit/prepaid
rate cap per
MOU
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES2
Size and type of facility
0–349 Jail ADP ................................................................................................
350–999 Jail ADP ............................................................................................
1,000+ Jail ADP ...............................................................................................
All Prisons ........................................................................................................
Collect rate
cap per MOU
as of effective
date
Collect rate
cap per MOU
as of July 1,
2017
Collect rate
cap per MOU
as of July 1,
2018
$0.49
0.49
0.49
0.14
$0.36
0.33
0.32
0.13
$0.22
0.16
0.14
0.11
$0.22
0.16
0.14
0.11
We prohibit any ancillary service
charges except for the following.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:49 Dec 17, 2015
Jkt 238001
PO 00000
Frm 00003
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
E:\FR\FM\18DER2.SGM
18DER2
79138
Federal Register / Vol. 80, No. 243 / Friday, December 18, 2015 / Rules and Regulations
TABLE TWO
Permitted ancillary service charges and taxes
Monetary cap per use/instruction
Applicable taxes and regulatory fees .......................................................
Provider shall pass these charges through to consumers directly with
no markup.
$3.00.
Provider shall directly pass through third-party financial transaction fees
with no markup, plus adopted, per-minute rate.
$5.95.
Automated payment fees .........................................................................
Fees for single-call and related services, e.g., direct bill to mobile
phone without setting up an account.
Live agent fee, i.e., phone payment or account set up with optional use
of a live operator.
Paper bill/statement fees (no charge permitted for electronic bills/statements).
Prepaid account funding minimums and maximums ...............................
Third-party financial transaction fees, e.g., MoneyGram, Western
Union, credit card processing fees and transfers from third party
commissary accounts.
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES2
10. These reforms supersede the
reforms adopted in the 2013 Order and
therefore will replace the interim
interstate rate caps and cost-based
framework previously adopted.
Accordingly, the extensive reforms we
adopt in this Order constitute material
changes of law and may also trigger
contractual force majeure clauses. To
comply with the new rules we adopt
herein, we therefore expect that ICS
providers may need to renegotiate many
of their contracts with correctional
facilities but note that ICS rates in
numerous states are already below our
adopted caps.
11. While the steps we take today are
significant, our work is not complete.
With that in mind, in today’s Further
Notice, we seek additional comment on
rates for international calls, promoting
competition in the ICS industry, the
benefits of a recurring Mandatory Data
Collection, as well as a requirement that
ICS providers file their ICS contracts
with the Commission, video visitation,
and other newer technologies to
increase ICS options, and seek
additional comment on the operations
and economic impacts of providing
those services as experienced by end
users, correctional facilities, and ICS
providers.
III. Background
12. In 2003, Martha Wright and her
fellow petitioners, current or former
prison inmates and their relatives and
legal counsel (Wright Petitioners or
Petitioners), filed a petition seeking a
rulemaking to address high longdistance ICS rates. The petition sought
to prohibit exclusive ICS contracts and
collect-call-only restrictions in
correctional facilities. In 2007, the
Petitioners filed an alternative
rulemaking petition, asking the
Commission to address high ICS rates
by requiring a debit-calling option in
correctional facilities, prohibiting per-
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:49 Dec 17, 2015
Jkt 238001
$2.00.
Prohibit prepaid account funding minimums and prohibit prepaid account funding maximums under $50.
Provider shall pass this charge through to end user directly, with no
markup.
call charges, and establishing rate caps
for interstate, interexchange ICS. The
Commission sought and received
comment on both petitions (Wright
Petitions).
13. In December 2012, in response to
the Wright Petitions, the Commission
adopted a Notice of Proposed
Rulemaking seeking comment on,
among other things, the proposals in the
Wright Petitions. The 2012 NPRM, 78
FR 4369, Jan. 22, 2013, proposed ways
to ‘‘balance the goal of ensuring
reasonable ICS rates for end users with
the security concerns and expense
inherent to ICS within the statutory
guidelines of sections 201(b) and 276 of
the Act.’’
14. On August 9, 2013, the
Commission adopted the Inmate Calling
Report and Order and FNPRM (2013
Order), finding that market forces were
not operating to ensure that interstate
ICS rates were just, reasonable, and fair.
The Commission concluded that, in
light of the absence of competitive
pressures working to keep rates just and
reasonable in the ICS market, the default
of cost-based regulation should apply.
As such, the Commission focused on
reforming interstate site commission
payments, rates, and ancillary service
charges. The Commission also
determined that site commission
payments ‘‘were not part of the cost of
providing ICS and therefore not
compensable in interstate ICS rates.’’
Analyzing data submitted into the
record and public data, the Commission
adopted interim per-minute interstate
ICS safe harbor caps of $0.12 for debit
and prepaid calls and $0.14 for collect
calls and hard rate caps of $0.21 for
debit and prepaid calls and $0.25 for
collect calls. The Commission gave
guidance to ICS providers regarding the
process for obtaining waivers of the
interim rate caps. The Commission also
required that ancillary service charges
be cost-based. At the time, the
PO 00000
Frm 00004
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
Commission declined to address
intrastate ICS, noting instead that it had
‘‘structured [its reforms] in a manner to
encourage . . . states to undertake
reform and sought comment on
intrastate reforms as part of the
FNPRM.’’ Finally, the record indicates
that as a result of our interim interstate
rate caps, interstate call volumes have
increased as much as 70 percent, while
interstate debit and prepaid rates have
decreased, on average, 32 percent and
interstate collect rates have decreased,
on average, 44 percent.
15. To enable the Commission to
enact ICS reform, the 2013 Order
adopted a Mandatory Data Collection
requiring ICS providers to file
information regarding the costs of
providing ICS, and an Annual Reporting
and Certification Requirement for ICS
rates. The Commission noted that the
Mandatory Data Collection would help
it ‘‘develop a permanent rate structure,
which could include more targeted
tiered rates in the future.’’ Through the
data collected pursuant to the
Mandatory Data Collection, the
Commission obtained significant cost
and operational data, including
ancillary service charge cost data, from
a variety of ICS providers representing
well over 85 percent of the ICS market.
16. Prior to the effective date of the
Order, the United States Court of
Appeals for the District of Columbia
Circuit stayed three rules adopted by the
Commission pending resolution of the
appeal, including the rule requiring
rates to be based on costs, the rule
adopting interim safe harbor rates, and
the rule requiring ICS providers to file
annual reports and certifications. The
court allowed other aspects of the 2013
Order to take effect, including the
interim interstate rate caps and
Mandatory Data Collection. Due to the
partial stay, the requirement that
ancillary service charges be based on
costs did not go into effect. As a result,
E:\FR\FM\18DER2.SGM
18DER2
Federal Register / Vol. 80, No. 243 / Friday, December 18, 2015 / Rules and Regulations
there have been no reforms to ancillary
service charges and fees and they have
continued to increase since the 2013
Order. The litigation has been held in
abeyance pending resolution of this
Order.
17. Since adoption of the 2013 Order,
the Commission has continued to
monitor the effects of its reforms on the
ICS industry and pursue additional
reform, including holding a workshop
entitled ‘‘Further Reform of Inmate
Calling Services’’ on July 9, 2014. The
workshop evaluated options for
additional ICS reforms, discussed the
effects of the Order, the role ancillary
service charges play in the ICS market,
the provision of ICS at different types of
facilities, and communications
technologies beyond traditional
payphone calling being deployed in
correctional facilities.
18. Second Further Notice of
Proposed Rulemaking. In October 2014,
the Commission adopted a Second
FNPRM (79 FR 69682) and sought
comment on several proposals in the
record urging comprehensive ICS
reform. The proposals the Commission
sought comment on suggested a variety
of ways to deal with issues identified in
the record, including rate caps, site
commission payments, and ancillary
fees that were offered by various entities
with differing perspectives in
addressing ICS reform. For example,
three ICS providers, GTL, Securus, and
Telmate, jointly filed a proposal to
comprehensively reform all aspects of
ICS. Several other individual ICS
providers, including CenturyLink and
Pay Tel, submitted their own proposals
for reform. The Wright Petitioners, along
with several public interest groups, also
urged the Commission to consider its
proposals for comprehensive reform.
Finally, the Commission sought
comment on costs incurred by
correctional facilities in the provision of
ICS and the data received in response to
the Mandatory Data Collection.
19. State Reforms. Several states have
undertaken ICS reform since the 2013
Order that reflect and are meant to
address circumstances specific to their
jurisdiction. The Alabama Public
Service Commission (Alabama PSC), for
example, adopted comprehensive ICS
reforms that include tiered intrastate
rate caps as well as a restricted number
of ancillary service charges at caps it
established. The Minnesota Department
of Corrections initiated a pilot program
in a limited number of correctional
facilities in which a flat rate of $0.07 per
minute is charged for all local and longdistance debit calls, bringing the cost of
a 15-minute call to $1.05, plus
applicable tax. New Jersey recently
entered into a new ICS contract
lowering rates for all interstate and
intrastate calls from state prison
facilities to $0.04348 a minute effective
August 25, 2015. The Ohio Department
of Rehabilitation and Correction
reduced rates to $0.05 per minute for all
ICS calls as of April 1, 2015. In
announcing its change, the Ohio
Department of Rehabilitation and
Correction noted that ‘‘[t]elephone calls
are one of the primary means of inmates
maintaining connections with family
and loved ones during incarceration;
maintaining these connections
positively influences behavior in prison
and the likelihood an offender will
succeed upon release from prison.’’
Inmates in the West Virginia Division of
Corrections now pay $0.032/minute for
all domestic ICS. We are pleased that
some states have taken positive steps to
reduce intrastate rates but remain
concerned that many intrastate rates
remain high and some have even
increased following the 2013 Order. The
actions we take today embrace previous
reforms and encourage additional states
to follow and enact more-tailored relief
in their states. The framework we adopt
today acts as a ceiling to enable reforms,
such as those undertaken by New Jersey,
Ohio, and West Virginia.
IV. Report and Order
A. Rate Caps That Comply With the
Statute
20. In this section we adopt tiered rate
caps for intrastate and interstate ICS that
will allow providers to continue to offer
safe and secure ICS while complying
with the requirements of the
Communications Act. These rate caps
79139
will apply to jails, prisons and
immigration detention facilities, secure
mental health facilities and juvenile
detention facilities.
21. A review of the record, including
over 100 comments and replies, costs
reported in response to the Mandatory
Data Collection, and various ex parte
filings, indicates that, notwithstanding
our interim caps on interstate rates,
more work still must be done to bring
ICS rates in conformance with the
mandates of the Communications Act.
The record demonstrates that many
interstate rates are not ‘‘just and
reasonable rates as required by Sections
201 and 202’’ and that many interstate
and intrastate rates result in
compensation that exceeds the fair
compensation permitted by section 276.
The Commission’s finding in the 2013
Order that the marketplace alone has
not ensured that ICS rates are just,
reasonable, and fair remains true today.
Nor has the risk of complaints filed
under section 208, or enforcement
actions pursuant to section 201(b) or
section 276, been sufficient to keep ICS
rates at levels that are just and
reasonable and fairly compensatory. We
therefore act, pursuant to our statutory
authority, to ensure that ICS rates
comply with the Communications Act,
while balancing the unique security
needs related to providing
telecommunications service in
correctional institutions and ensuring
that ICS providers receive fair
compensation and a reasonable return
on investment.
22. Specifically, we adopt a rate cap
of $0.22/MOU for debit and prepaid
calls from jails with an ADP of 0–349;
a $0.16/MOU cap for debit and prepaid
calls from jails with an ADP of 350–999;
and a $0.14/MOU cap for debit and
prepaid calls from jails with an ADP of
1,000 or more. Debit and prepaid calls
from prisons will be capped at a rate of
$0.11/MOU. Collect calls from jail
facilities will be capped at $0.49/MOU
and collect calls from prison facilities
will be capped at $0.14/MOU until July
1, 2017, and then transition down on an
annual basis to the applicable debit/
prepaid rate cap as described herein.
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES2
TABLE THREE
Debit/prepaid
rate cap per
MOU
Size and type of facility
0–349 Jail ADP ................................................................................................
350–999 Jail ADP ............................................................................................
1,000+ Jail ADP ...............................................................................................
All Prisons ........................................................................................................
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:49 Dec 17, 2015
Jkt 238001
PO 00000
Frm 00005
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
Collect rate
cap per MOU
as of effective
date
Collect rate
cap per MOU
as of July 1,
2017
Collect rate
cap per MOU
as of July 1,
2018
$0.49
0.49
0.49
0.14
$0.36
0.33
0.32
0.13
$0.22
0.16
0.14
0.11
$0.22
0.16
0.14
0.11
E:\FR\FM\18DER2.SGM
18DER2
79140
Federal Register / Vol. 80, No. 243 / Friday, December 18, 2015 / Rules and Regulations
23. In the subsections that follow, we
describe our methodology for adopting
these rate caps. Specifically, we: (1)
Discuss the decision to adopt a tiered
structure that distinguishes between
jails and prisons, and, within jails,
based upon ADP, (2) describe the
reasoning for adopting the specified
tiers, (3) describe the methodology and
analysis supporting the specific rate
caps adopted, using a carefully
considered combination of analysis of
the Mandatory Data Collection
(including evidence suggesting that
some providers submitted inflated cost
data), successful reform in certain states,
experience with the interim rate caps,
and other data in the voluminous record
of this proceeding, (4) explain the need
for a temporary, separate rate for collect
calls, which will phase out over a twoyear period to equalize the rate for these
calls with those of debit/prepaid calls,
(5) reject per-call/per-connection
charges and flat-rate calling as
inherently unjust, unreasonable, and
unfair in contravention of the statute,
and (6) explain our legal authority to
adopt these reforms.
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES2
1. Tiered Structure Distinguishing
Between Jails and Prisons
24. Before determining the specific
amount of any rate caps, a key question
before us is the appropriate rate
structure for ICS—i.e., whether there
should be a single unitary rate for
inmate calling services regardless of the
facility type or size. We find in this
Order that the record supports
distinguishing between the type of
facility (jails vs. prisons) as well as, for
jails, tiering based on the size of the
facility.
a. Justification for Separate Tiers
25. In both the 2013 FNPRM (78 FR
68005) and Second FNPRM, the
Commission sought comment on rate
tiering. In the Second FNPRM, the
Commission also sought comment on
the appropriate definition of ‘‘prison’’
and ‘‘jail,’’ and on the potential
suitability of rate tiering based on
differences between jails and prisons as
well as population size. As discussed
below, there was substantial record
support for such an approach.
26. Background. Some commenters
support differentiating rates between
different facility types or sizes. For
example, Petitioners assert that the
‘‘cost of providing service in these large
facilities is substantially less than the
cost of providing service in small jails,
and that ICS providers can serve these
larger facilities with less administrative
costs.’’ Other commenters assert that
‘‘characteristics unique to different
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:49 Dec 17, 2015
Jkt 238001
types of facilities’’ should lead to rate
tiering. Some commenters contend that
it costs more to provide ICS in smaller
jails than it does in larger jails. These
parties argue that a one-size-fits-all rate
cap will not work, ignores the record
and likely will lead to a violation of
sections 201 and 276 of the Act. We
note that the Alabama PSC recently
adopted rate tiers tied to facility type,
with separate rates for jails and prisons.
27. The Los Angeles Sheriff’s
Department advocates that the
Commission ‘‘resist the temptation to
set uniform rates’’ because the
differences in security requirements,
inmates, age, infrastructure and
maintenance needs of facilities must be
accounted for in the Commission’s
decision-making process.’’ The
California State Sheriff’s Association
echoes these concerns, explaining that
in California, the smallest jail can hold
a maximum of 14 inmates, while the
largest jail can hold a maximum of over
14,000 inmates, and contends that
accounting for these differences ‘‘is
much more important and realistic than
attempting to craft a single ‘solution’ for
uniformity’s sake.’’ NCIC also supports
tiering in order to ‘‘balance the needs of
inmates, their families, correction
facilities and ICS providers.’’
28. Moreover, some commenters
assert that, without tiering, providers
serving small- to medium-sized jails
‘‘would likely be forced out of the
market, particularly if the larger
companies cross-subsidize between lowcost (Prison) and high-cost (Jail)
facilities’’ because it is more costly to
providers to serve smaller facilities (as
confirmed by our analysis of the
Mandatory Data Collection).
Additionally, there is evidence that
some large ICS providers refuse to bid
on contracts to serve only smaller
institutions—suggesting again that the
cost structure of serving smaller
institutions is higher than that of larger
institutions.
29. Other commenters, however,
disagree with a tiered rate approach and
counter that the Commission should
continue to impose unitary rate caps,
similar to the current, interim rate caps.
These commenters contend that unitary
rates are less complex to understand
and to administer, and that no real
difference exists between the cost of
serving jails and prisons. For instance,
GTL and CenturyLink contend that
‘‘there is no clean proxy for cost that
could be relied upon to create tiers.’’
Additionally, some commenters argue
that adopting tiers based on a prison/jail
distinction would be arbitrary,
especially as many large providers serve
both prisons and jails. Securus claims
PO 00000
Frm 00006
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
that ‘‘to adopt vastly different calling
rates based on that empty [jails vs.
prisons] distinction would constitute
dissimilar treatment of customers that
plainly are similarly situated,’’ which it
asserts is ‘‘unjustifiable.’’
30. Discussion. Based on the record
and market evidence, we find that
tiering based on jail versus prison is
appropriate, and therefore reject
proposals that we should adopt a
unitary rate similar to the unitary rate
caps adopted in the 2013 Order.
31. In the 2013 Order, the
Commission found it appropriate to
adopt interim unitary rates for a number
of reasons. First, the Commission
observed the challenges to setting
interim rates, including the fact that
although the Commission relied on the
best data available to it at the time, that
data represented a very small subset of
data, and included cost data from
locations with varying cost and call
volume characteristics. Second, the
Commission noted that it considered
setting different rate caps based on the
size or type of correctional facility, but
stated that ‘‘the record contains
conflicting assertions as to what those
distinctions should be.’’ Instead, the
Commission adopted interim interstate
rate caps ‘‘for correctional facilities
generally,’’ ‘‘based on the highest cost
data available in the record, which [it]
anticipated will ensure fair
compensation for providers servicing
jails and prisons alike.’’ Finally, the
Commission noted that unitary rates
were the focus of the original petition
for rulemaking and the focus of the
majority of comments at that time. Upon
release of that item, the Commission
adopted the Mandatory Data Collection
to ‘‘enable [it] to take further action to
reform rates, including developing a
permanent cap or safe harbor for
interstate rates, as well as to inform our
evaluation of other rate reform options
in the Further Notice.’’ The responses to
the Mandatory Data Collection have
greatly expanded the cost data available
to us for analysis.
32. We conclude that adopting tiered
interstate and intrastate rates accounts
for the differences in costs to ICS
providers serving smaller, higher-cost
facilities, such as the vast majority of
jails. A similar concern applies to the
potential for over-compensating ICS
providers serving larger, lower cost
facilities, such as very large jails and
prisons. We agree with those
commenters who assert that the $0.20
and $0.24 rate caps proposed in the
Joint Provider Proposal could result in
excessive profits for the largest
providers to the detriment of end users
who would have to pay inflated rates far
E:\FR\FM\18DER2.SGM
18DER2
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 80, No. 243 / Friday, December 18, 2015 / Rules and Regulations
above the providers’ costs. For example,
in the public portion of its cost data
filing Securus noted that its overall cost
per minute across all of its ICS contracts
is $0.1776. GTL similarly provided its
overall cost per minute across all ICS
contracts, which it estimated at $0.1341.
These averaged, self-reported, costs are
well below the $0.20 and $0.24 rate caps
proposed by these same providers in the
Joint Provider Proposal.
33. The record, and our analysis of
costs reported in response to the
Mandatory Data Collection, support rate
tiering because, holding other factors
constant, the costs to serve prisons are
lower than to serve jails. This is not
surprising. Prisons typically have more
stable, long-term inmate populations.
For example, there is less than one
percent inmate churn in prisons per
week compared to an average of 58
percent inmate churn in jails. The
record suggests that higher churn rates
increase costs to process and grant a
new inmate access to calling services,
and also when an inmate exits a facility.
The record also indicates that prison
inmates make fewer but longer calls and
providers appear to incur fewer bad
debt costs when serving prisons.
34. We also find that economies of
scale, such as the recovering of fixed
ICS costs over a larger number of
inmates, support the tiering approach
we adopt today. In the 2013 Order, the
Commission noted that unit or average
costs of providing ICS were decreasing
as scale increased because of, for
example, centralized application of
security measures and ‘‘the ability to
centrally provision across multiple
facilities.’’ More generally, providers of
ICS typically incur a range of costs that
do not scale with volume, sometimes
known as fixed costs. For example, the
cost of a calling center is largely shared
over a provider’s entire operations, so
the unit costs of the calling center fall
quickly as call volumes increase.
Similarly, the cost of connecting a
facility to the ICS provider’s network
increases at a much lower rate when
minutes of use increase. Indeed, in
general, the incremental cost of a
minute of use is almost zero. The
Kansas Department of Corrections
echoes these findings, stating in its
support for rate tiering that ‘‘[t]he cost
to provide an ICS is largely driven by
the size of a facility and length of stay.
Larger facilities benefit from the
economies of scale that allows agencies
and ICS providers to spread the cost
among a larger population.’’ Pay Tel
also reports that there are material fixed
costs in providing ICS which can be
distributed across larger facilities, like
prisons, more readily than smaller
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:49 Dec 17, 2015
Jkt 238001
facilities such as jails. Indeed, many ICS
providers currently offer service to
multiple facilities under one contract,
reflecting the benefits of centralizing
fixed costs across a larger base of
customers. Lastly, ongoing industry
consolidation supports our finding that
there are economies of scale in the
provision of ICS, i.e., the incentive to
become more efficient through scale is
an incentive for providers to enter into
mergers.
35. Recent state reforms also support
tiering. Indeed, the Alabama PSC
recently adopted rate tiers tied to
facility type with separate rates adopted
for jails and prisons. In December 2014,
the Alabama PSC adopted a rate
structure that ‘‘provides lower rates [for
prisons] in recognition that the perminute costs for service in prisons is
lower than it is for jails.’’ In order ‘‘to
ensure ample opportunity to correct any
funding shortfalls resulting from
potential reductions in site
commissions,’’ the adopted rate caps
included a two-year phase-down period
from $0.30/minute to $0.25/minute for
collect and debit/prepaid calling from
jails and $0.25/minute to $0.21/minute
for debit/prepaid calling from prisons,
while the prison collect rate stays at the
initial $0.25/minute rate cap.
36. We disagree with assertions that a
tiered rate structure would be difficult
for the Commission to administer, for
ICS providers to implement, and for
correctional officials to oversee. Those
commenters who make such assertions
already charge different rates across
different ICS contracts and provide no
real evidence or support for why rate
tiers would be any more difficult or
challenging than their current
approaches.
37. For all of these reasons, we
conclude that adopting rate tiers based
on facility type as well as size, or ADP,
allows us to recognize the differences in
the costs of serving facilities of different
types as well as providing multiple
checks to prevent gaming or
manipulation as discussed below.
Tiering will limit ‘‘the impact of the
higher rates to those facilities most in
need, while ensuring that the vast
majority of ICS calls are charged at a
rate commensurate with the cost of
providing the ICS service.’’
b. Determination of Facility Type and
Average Daily Population
38. Defining Jails and Prisons. Given
that our rates will differ for prisons and
jails, it is necessary to define these key
terms with specificity. The Commission
sought comment on defining the terms
‘‘prison’’ and ‘‘jail’’ in the Second
FNPRM. Subsequent to the Second
PO 00000
Frm 00007
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
79141
FNPRM, several commenters provided
suggested definitions. We have
considered these submissions and adopt
the following definitions.
39. Specifically, for purposes of this
proceeding a jail is defined as the
facility of a local, state, or federal law
enforcement agency that is used
primarily to hold individuals who are:
(1) Awaiting adjudication of criminal
charges, (2) post-conviction and
committed to confinement for sentences
of one year or less, or (3) postconviction and are awaiting transfer to
another facility. The term also includes
city, county or regional facilities that
have contracted with a private company
to manage day-to-day operations;
privately-owned and operated facilities
primarily engaged in housing city,
county or regional inmates; and
facilities used to detain individuals
pursuant to a contract with U.S.
Immigration and Customs Enforcement
(ICE) and facilities operated by ICE. For
purposes of this proceeding a prison is
defined as a facility operated by a
territorial, state, or federal agency that is
used primarily to confine individuals
convicted of felonies and sentenced to
terms in excess of one year. The term
also includes public and private
facilities that provide housing to other
agencies such as the State Departments
of Correction and the Federal Bureau of
Prisons; and facilities that would
otherwise fall under the definition of a
jail but in which the majority of inmates
are post-conviction or are committed to
confinement for sentences of longer
than one year.
40. Facility or Institution. The record
indicates concern that some ICS
providers may try to take advantage of
the rate tiering structure we adopt in
this Order by increasing the number of
‘‘facilities’’ in which they are allowed to
charge the higher rate caps adopted for
smaller jails above. For example, ICS
providers may do this, commenters
explain, by seeking to divide a detention
facility into sub-units, such as wards or
wings. The Commission sought
comment on these possibilities in the
Second FNPRM. Comments received in
response confirmed that concerns that
providers might try to game our rules
were justified. Such gaming would be
contrary to this Order, and would serve
to frustrate the underlying purposes of
sections 201 and 276 of the
Communications Act. It would allow
providers to appear as though they are
serving smaller jails than they actually
are, even though they achieve
economies of scale by combining
multiple small facilities under a single
contract, because they are able to
centralize services, like call monitoring
E:\FR\FM\18DER2.SGM
18DER2
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES2
79142
Federal Register / Vol. 80, No. 243 / Friday, December 18, 2015 / Rules and Regulations
and recording, thereby reducing their
overall costs. In order to establish and
maintain just, reasonable, and fair ICS
compensation, we must consider these
issues and take steps to ensure that our
adopted tiered rate caps cannot be
undone by gaming.
41. As such, we find that a jail, as
defined above, and a prison, as defined
above, cannot be divided into multiple
wings, units, or wards by, for example,
for the purpose of taking advantage of
our tiered rate caps. If interested parties
believe such gaming is occurring they
may bring the issue to the Commission’s
attention, at which time the
Commission will review the totality of
the circumstances (e.g., treatment of the
facility under state law, relevant
contracts, physical attachment or
proximity of units, etc.) to determine
whether unlawful gaming has occurred.
42. Average Daily Population for Jails.
As an initial matter, for purposes of the
reforms adopted in this Order, the
initial average daily population will be
the sum of all inmates in a facility each
day in the 12-month period prior to the
effective date of this Order divided by
the number of days in the year. This
definition is consistent with that used
by the Department of Justice’s Bureau of
Jail Statistics. We note that correctional
institutions often publicly report their
ADP. This publicly-reported population
data should be used, where available, to
determine the appropriate ADP for a
facility. Going forward, when the
relevant ADP is not publicly reported,
beginning with January 31, 2017, the
ADP will be calculated on a calendar
year basis as the sum of all inmates in
a facility each day between January 1
and December 31 of the previous year,
divided by the number of days in the
year. The applicable ADP will then be
determined as of January 31 of each year
pursuant to the ADP from the previous
year and will remain in effect
throughout that year. Consistent with
this approach, if a correctional facility
adds a new building or wing to a
facility, the inmate population of the
new wing will not be accounted for
immediately. Rather, the inmate
population of a new building or wing
will first be considered in the
calculations for ADP to be applied in
the following year. For example, if a
new wing is established anytime
between January 1, 2017 and December
31, 2017, its inmate population during
this time frame will be included in the
ADP to be applied on January 31, 2018.
We find this to be the most
administratively efficient and feasible
option, rather than potentially having
numerous rate changes during a
calendar year. New buildings or wings
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:49 Dec 17, 2015
Jkt 238001
may not be filled immediately, and it
may take some time before population
levels in a newly-established wing
increase enough to push the facility as
a whole into a new tier. We find these
detailed definitions are necessary to
ensure that end users are charged just,
reasonable, and fair rates and that ICS
providers receive fair compensation for
the costs they incur in providing ICS to
smaller and larger facilities.
43. Categorization of Certain HighCost Facilities. In the Second FNPRM
the Commission sought comment on
suggestions that it either exclude from
any adopted rate caps what are reported
to be high-cost facilities, such as
juvenile detention facilities or secure
mental health facilities, or provide a
blanket waiver for such facilities. While
the Commission did not request that
providers separately calculate and
report their costs for providing service
to secure mental health facilities or
juvenile detention facilities outside of
jails or prisons in response to the
Mandatory Data Collection, we agree
with commenters that these facilities
may be more costly to serve due to the
smaller number of inmates. This is also
consistent with our analysis above. We
therefore conclude that the costs of
providing ICS to juvenile detention
facilities and secure mental health
facilities are more akin to providing
service to jail facilities. To the extent
that juvenile detention facilities and
secure mental health facilities operate
outside of jail or prison institutions,
they will be subject to the jail rate caps
adopted herein.
2. Tiers for Jails
44. After placing issues relating to the
Mandatory Data Collection out for
public comment, the Bureau reviewed
written comments, met with interested
parties, and adopted a template for
submission of required data in the
Mandatory Data Collection. In it, the
Bureau directed ICS providers to
document applicable costs and fees by
‘‘contract size.’’ Potential contract size
categories for jails include 0–99, 100–
349, 349–999, and 1000 ADP and
greater, and potential categories for
prisons include 1–4999, 5000–19,999,
and 20,000 ADP and greater.
45. The Commission sought comment
on proposed rate tiering in the Second
FNPRM. Pay Tel asserts that it supports
three rate tiers, one for ‘‘small-tomedium sized jails (less than 350 ADP)
based on ‘demonstrated operational and
functional differences between prisons
and jails—and the cost differences
associated with [the] provision of ICS
therein.’’’ Petitioners support a twotiered structure and suggest rate caps for
PO 00000
Frm 00008
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
facilities with 0–349 ADP and facilities
with 350 and over ADP in order to take
into account the ‘‘alleged higher costs
incurred by small jails. The Joint
Provider Proposal does not favor any
rate tiers. Securus asserts that if the
Commission adopts a tiered rate
structure, ‘‘the tiers should be defined
in a way that account[s] not only for
ADP but also differences in the
investment required to serve a site. . . .
And, as Securus previously has stated,
ADP must be very closely defined such
that carriers cannot game the system in
the way that they report those figures.’’
46. In this Order we adopt rate tiers
based on the following ADP for jails: 0–
349, 350–999, and 1,000 and greater. We
adopt these rate tiers for jails because
we find that they most closely resemble
the breakdown between small-tomedium jails, large jails, and very large,
or mega-jails. We have decided not to
include a 0–99 ADP breakdown in the
rate tiers in part because, according to
the Bureau of Justice Statistics, jails
with an ADP under 99 make up less
than 10 percent of the inmate
population. We also believe that
adopting fewer tiers than those
requested in response to the Mandatory
Data Collection responds to comments
in the record expressing concern over
potential confusion and burden of
multiple rates. By adopting these tiers
for jails, we conclude that our rate caps
will most closely conform to the costs
as filed in the record. As a group, jails
are more varied than prisons and, as we
have discussed herein, there are
economies of scale to be gained as
facility size increases. Finally, as
discussed below, the data received in
response to the Mandatory Data
Collection support these tiers.
47. Below we explain how we have
determined that our prescribed rates
will allow efficient providers to recover
their costs. We rely principally upon: (1)
Analysis of data received in response to
the Mandatory Data Collection, which
shows that firms operating efficiently
would earn substantial profits under our
prescribed rates, (2) evidence suggesting
that providers’ reported costs in
response to the mandatory data
collection are overstated, and (3) other
evidence in the record, including ICS
providers’ provision of service in
jurisdictions with rates lower than those
we prescribe here.
3. Determination of Specific Rate Caps
48. Having determined the basic
structure of rate caps, we describe the
methodology for the specific rate caps
within that structure. Specifically, we
find that the following rate caps will
ensure that ICS rates are just,
E:\FR\FM\18DER2.SGM
18DER2
Federal Register / Vol. 80, No. 243 / Friday, December 18, 2015 / Rules and Regulations
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES2
reasonable, and fair for inmates, their
families and loved ones, as well as the
ICS providers, and will incorporate the
costs associated with the necessary
security protocols: $0.22/MOU for debit
and prepaid calls from jails with an
ADP of 0–349; $0.16/MOU for debit and
prepaid calls from jails with an ADP of
350–999; and $0.14/MOU for debit and
prepaid calls from jails with an ADP of
1,000 or more. Debit and prepaid calls
from prisons will be capped at a rate of
$0.11/MOU. Collect calls from jails will
be capped at $0.49/MOU and collect
calls from prisons will be capped at
$0.14/MOU until July 1, 2017, and then
transition down to the appropriate
debit/prepaid rate cap.
a. Marketplace Evidence of Rates in
Certain States
49. Evidence of rates at the state level
generally provides further support that
the rate caps we adopt today allow
sufficient room for providers to earn a
fair profit. As noted above, Ohio
eliminated site commissions and
reduced ICS rates by 75 percent to $0.05
for Ohio Department of Rehabilitation
and Correction (ODRC) facilities. West
Virginia’s Division of Corrections
recently reviewed bids without regard to
site commissions offered by the bidders
(i.e., the DOC did not take site
commissions into account in deciding
the winning bidder). New Jersey
recently awarded an ICS contract for
state prisons that eliminated site
commission payments and reduced
rates below $0.05 per minute, yet the
winning bidder, GTL, reported to the
Commission average 2012 through 2013
ICS costs of [BEGIN CONFIDENTIAL]
[END CONFIDENTIAL]. The
Pennsylvania Department of Corrections
(DOC) contracted with Securus at a
$0.059 per-minute rate for all ICS and
the elimination of all ancillary fees,
while offering a 35 percent site
commission, even though Securus
reported to the Commission that its
average cost of providing ICS over 2012
and 2013 was [BEGIN CONFIDENTIAL]
[END CONFIDENTIAL]. Similarly, in
New Hampshire, the state DOC lowered
intrastate rates to less than $0.06 per
minute with a 20 percent site
commission. That providers bid for
these contracts, and supply ICS at rates
consistent with these constraints,
strongly suggests that efficient providers
can provide ICS at rates closer to $0.05
per minute—less than half of our lowest
rate cap of $0.11 per minute. This is not
surprising, as a per-minute rate of
approximately $0.05 per minute
approximates the lowest average perminute costs reported to us. We observe
that it is unlikely that any provider
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:49 Dec 17, 2015
Jkt 238001
would supply any state if the rates
allowed in those states did not at least
cover the incremental costs of supplying
each of those states, which further
suggests that reported costs may be
inflated. We also note that no provider
clearly argued that such rate levels are
the result of cross-subsidization, and
there is no data in the record to support
such a conclusion. While one provider
made statements unsupported by data
that might be so interpreted, those
statements are too vague to evaluate.
b. Analysis of Data Received in
Response to the Mandatory Data
Collection
50. Rate Methodology. In the 2013
Order, the Commission adopted the
Mandatory Data Collection to enable it
‘‘to take further action to reform rates,
including developing a permanent cap
or safe harbor for interstate rates, as well
as to inform our evaluation of other rate
reform options in the Further Notice.’’
In 2014, the Wireline Competition
Bureau (Bureau) developed a template
and related instructions for ICS
providers to use in responding to the
Mandatory Data Collection. The
Commission also provided notice of the
data collection, its due date, and
information on contacting Bureau staff
available to answer specific questions
on how to comply with the filing
requirement and the template and
instructions. The instructions, template,
and other related material were posted
on the Commission’s Web site, and the
data collection due date was announced
by Public Notice which was also
published in the Federal Register, 79 FR
35956, Nov. 21, 2014. Responsive data
were received in August 2014.
51. The Commission directed the
Bureau to create the template in a
manner intended to allow a provider to
include all costs incurred in the
provision of ICS. Without limiting or
restricting costs or cost categories, the
Bureau directed providers to report their
ICS-related costs for
telecommunications, equipment, and
security, as well as any costs not
captured in these categories (i.e., ‘‘other
costs’’). The Commission directed
providers to submit the data for fiscal
years 2012, 2013, and 2014, which
provided the two most recent years of
actual data and one year of partial actual
and partial forecasted data. Providers
were required to report intrastate,
interstate and international ICS cost
data in the aggregate for debit, prepaid,
and collect calling services. For each
service, providers were required to
identify which costs were direct or
common, and to allocate costs by
facility type and size. Providers also
PO 00000
Frm 00009
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
79143
submitted call volume data (MOU and
number of calls) for each category. The
Commission received data filings from
14 of the 25 anticipated ICS provider
respondents. We estimate that the 14
responding providers together represent
over 90 percent of the market.
52. The debit and prepaid rate caps
we adopt are based on 2012 and 2013
data submitted by the 14 responding
providers. The caps rely on the 2012
and 2013 data because it represents
actual, rather than projected, data, and
allows averaging across the two years to
account for cost variations that may
occur between the years. Costs per
minute were calculated using a
weighted average per minute cost
(which is the same as dividing aggregate
costs (i.e., the entirety of all costs
reported by the providers for any
category) by aggregate minutes of use in
that category). This prevents small
outliers from having a disproportionate
impact on our analysis.
53. Based on the record and our
analysis described below, we believe the
applicable rate caps will ensure just,
reasonable and fair compensation for
ICS. We have relied on the cost data and
allocations as submitted by ICS
providers in calculating these rate caps.
We note that the providers cost data
reflect their determinations about how
to allocate certain common costs, such
as call centers and back-office
operations. It is generally understood
that an economically rational provider
will serve a facility if it can recover its
incremental cost of doing so, which the
record and our analysis indicate will be
the case. We take the data at face value,
even though the analysis shows that
there is significant evidence—both from
our own analysis and commenters’
critiques—suggesting that the reported
costs are overstated. We also find
support in the record evidence of
increased demand and additional scale
efficiencies, which are not included in
our quantitative analysis. Our analysis
and the record evidence support our
conclusion that efficient providers
would be able to operate profitably
under our rate caps.
54. Discussion and Analysis. Based on
the record and our own analysis
described below, we find that our
prescribed rate caps as outlined above
are more than sufficient to allow
providers to recover efficiently-incurred
ICS costs (excluding reported
commissions).
55. The record supports our
conclusion. Coleman Bazelon,
economics consultant for the Wright
Petitioners, analyzed our rate caps and
concluded that they ‘‘will largely cover
the individual ICS providers’ costs in
E:\FR\FM\18DER2.SGM
18DER2
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES2
79144
Federal Register / Vol. 80, No. 243 / Friday, December 18, 2015 / Rules and Regulations
providing service.’’ [BEGIN
CONFIDENTIAL] [END
CONFIDENTIAL] The Bazelon
economic analysis does not take into
account the evidence that lower rates
will spur demand, such that the vast
majority of the industry costs will be
covered by the rates adopted today.
56. ICSolutions, an ICS provider,
states that it ‘‘can comply with the
proposed rules’’ and notes that this
‘‘strongly suggests that any entity
failures in the industry are likely a
result of inefficient operations.’’ NCIC
also supports our rate caps. Praeses
‘‘believes that Providers will generally
be able to provide services pursuant to
these rate caps at a profit.’’ Praeses also
reports that interstate call volume and
resulting revenue have increased since
our 2013 interim reform, with facilities
operated by its clients seeing
approximately 76 percent interstate call
volume increases and overall interstate
revenue growth of approximately twelve
percent. This is unsurprising, as
reduced prices typically lead to higher
volume. ICSolutions reports seeing call
volumes increase ‘‘by as much as 150%,
and revenues increase by about 30%’’
when it implements lower call rates. In
addition, our rate caps are generally
higher than rates that have been adopted
in several states that have undertaken
reform and there is no evidence in the
record that such rates have made
provision of ICS unprofitable. Also,
nothing in the record suggests that states
that have adopted such reforms are
different from those states that have not
adopted reform with respect to either
costs or revenues.
57. Our own analysis likewise shows
that the rate caps will permit just,
reasonable, and fair recovery for the
provision of ICS. Our approach is
conservative in its analysis of both costs
and call volumes (and hence revenues).
It includes all the reported data,
assumes they do not overstate costs, and
takes no account of likely increases in
call volumes that our rates would
induce, thereby understating expected
revenues. This analysis thus likely
reflects a worst-case scenario, and, as
discussed below, even in the worst-case
scenario, our rates are fair and
reasonable.
58. Costs. Our analysis of costs
supports our conclusion that efficient
providers will be assured just,
reasonable, and fair compensation
under our rate caps. In particular, based
on the unaudited costs for 2012 and
2013 reported by the 14 respondents to
the Commission’s Mandatory Data
Collection, the lowest rate cap we
prescribe ($0.11) is greater than the
average per minute cost of each of the
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:49 Dec 17, 2015
Jkt 238001
more efficient reporting providers. Two
of these providers are quite small, and
operate in relatively small jails only. As
a result, as discussed below, the
expected efficient cost of these small
providers on a per minute basis is likely
higher than the efficient costs larger
reporting providers face, which implies
that larger providers should also be able
to operate at a profit at our prescribed
prices. We recognize that some
providers may supply a range of
services that go beyond ICS, and the
prices that they charge may be used to
cross-subsidize these services. However,
we do not consider it appropriate for
non-ICS services, such as locationmonitoring, to be paid for by inmates
and their families and friends through
ICS rates.
59. Further, we find that providers
reporting high costs could recover those
costs and receive just, reasonable, and
fair compensation under our rate caps
through increased efficiencies. Our
analysis suggests that providers
generally may have been over inclusive
in reporting their costs and that the
supply of ICS is not fully competitive,
implying that the adopted rate caps are
conservative. We also note that no
providers have submitted evidence that
their higher costs may be attributable to
higher-quality or more technologicallyadvanced ICS.
60. Other evidence reinforces our
view that respondents’ reported costs
may in some cases exceed economic
costs, and lead us to conclude that our
prescribed rate caps will allow efficient
firms to recover their economic costs,
including a reasonable return. For
example, the average per-paid minute
cost of each of the seven largest firms
substantially exceeds the average perpaid minute average cost of each of
three smaller providers. This data point
suggests these larger firms are either
economically inefficient or that they
overstated their costs of ICS provision.
On one hand, if there were economies
of scale or constant returns to scale in
production of calls or call minutes of
use, then larger firms would have lower
or the same average costs as the smaller
firms, implying that these larger firms’
reported costs are above efficient levels.
On the other hand, if there were
diseconomies of scale (that is, the
average per-minute cost rises with MOU
volumes), then these firms are
inefficiently large (they would be more
effective broken up into smaller firms),
and we should not subsidize that
anomaly.
61. More generally, we find above that
average costs should fall with the
provider’s size. However, the reported
data (implausibly) show only a very
PO 00000
Frm 00010
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
weak negative relationship between
average costs and the number of calls or
MOU. Similarly, the data (again
implausibly) do not support a priori
assumptions about underlying costs. For
example, regression analysis indicates
that the firms’ costs were highly
correlated with different measures of
MOU, type of call, and facilities
serviced. However, in most
specifications the coefficients associated
with the MOU and call variables were
implausible: they were typically well
above the expected marginal cost of an
additional MOU. Further, in some
specifications, the differences between
the marginal costs of different types of
calls were implausibly large and
statistically significant. Both of these
facts (the lack of scale economies in call
production and minutes of use and
oddities about reported marginal costs)
suggest that the data do not reflect the
actual economic costs of supply and
lead us to doubt the extent to which
reported costs accurately reflect efficient
costs. Additionally, reinforcing our view
that reported costs are inefficiently high,
there is evidence that some of the
providers’ costs include services that are
not directly related to the provision of
ICS. In short, all these observations
make it all the more likely that our
prescribed rate caps would allow an
efficient provider to earn economic
profits.
62. There is also evidence that
competition to supply ICS may not
always be robust, which in turn suggests
providers are able to earn more than
economic costs, and if faced with lower
revenues, may remain profitable. The
most important evidence in this last
respect is that the providers’ unaudited
cost data show that roughly similarly
situated providers have substantially
different costs. This not only suggests
that the higher cost providers are
unlikely to be economically efficient,
but also that if they were to operate
more efficiently, they would have no
difficulties in recovering their economic
costs. For example, a lack of robust
competition would explain why the
reported cost data does not seem
reflective of underlying costs (a result
that is inconsistent with effective
competition). Analysis of that data also
finds a tight relationship between costs
and output levels, both when
commissions are included and
excluded. This suggests a high degree of
homogeneity in the industry between
reported costs (with and without
commissions) and output. One might
expect such results if all bids for ICS
were either competitive or noncompetitive, but, as noted, other aspects
E:\FR\FM\18DER2.SGM
18DER2
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 80, No. 243 / Friday, December 18, 2015 / Rules and Regulations
of the cost data are inconsistent with
competition, and other evidence
suggests competition, if it exists, is not
found everywhere.
63. Two of the six smallest
responding providers when ranked by
paid MOU would earn substantial
imputed profits at our prescribed rates.
For example, over 2012 and 2013,
[BEGIN CONFIDENTIAL] [END
CONFIDENTIAL] had an average per
paid minute cost of $0.05 (and a similar
average per all minute cost) when
rounded to the nearest $0.05, earning
imputed profits of well over 200
percent. Similarly, in 2012 and 2013,
[BEGIN CONFIDENTIAL] [END
CONFIDENTIAL] had an average perpaid minute cost of $0.10 when rounded
to the nearest $0.05, earning imputed
profits in excess of 100 percent.
64. In contrast, our conservative
approach imputed reductions in
providers’ ability to recover costs under
our initial rate caps to seven of the
reporting providers, but we find that all
of these providers would be highly
profitable if their cost structures
resembled those of the two small
efficient firms we identified. Four of
these are among the six smallest
responding providers. Each reported
average per-paid minute costs over 2012
and 2013 of $0.25 or higher. That is, in
all cases their average per-paid minute
costs were more than two and a half
times, and in some cases several
multiples of, the highest paid MOU
average cost of the two small providers
with imputed profits. Consequently, if
these four providers’ average costs were
halved, so that they still exceeded those
of the two small providers with imputed
profits, then all four would operate at a
profit given our conservative revenue
assumptions. The remaining three
providers with imputed reductions in
cost recovery are considerably larger
than the two small providers with
imputed profits discussed above, and
more than one supplies services in
prisons as well as jails. Yet, each has an
average per-paid minute cost that is at
least three times as high as that of
[BEGIN CONFIDENTIAL] [END
CONFIDENTIAL] (which we found to
have large imputed profits). Again, if
these providers’ costs were considerably
closer to, but still well above those of
[BEGIN CONFIDENTIAL] [END
CONFIDENTIAL], then they would be
able to earn profits while charging rates
consistent with our prescribed rate caps.
In the two subsequent years, providers’
ability to recover costs would change,
but in all cases if these providers were
as efficient as the two efficient providers
discussed above, they would earn an
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:49 Dec 17, 2015
Jkt 238001
economic profit in all of the years
discussed.
65. Revenue. Turning to revenue, our
analysis likewise demonstrates that our
rate caps permit fair, reasonable, and
just compensation. Once again, we take
the provider’s data as filed despite the
evidence that they are overstated.
Moreover, even assuming the same call
volumes as experienced in 2012 and
2013, no other revenue sources, and no
improved efficiency in service
provision, we can impute in the initial
year that all providers, if operating
efficiently, would be profitable under
our prescribed rate caps. With more
realistic assumptions (greater call
volumes, revenues from ancillary
services, and productivity
improvements), it is likely that any
provider facing imputed revenue
reductions in the range of 10 percent
would remain profitable even if its
reported costs were not overstated (and
we find to the contrary). For example,
for the reasons described below and
based on record filings, capping rates is
likely to increase minutes of use, thus
raising revenues, and this would likely
make up for such imputed reduction in
revenue. The few remaining providers
potentially could face larger imputed
reductions in revenue (assuming their
reported costs were efficient). However,
these providers have reported costs
significantly higher than the industry
average, even more strongly suggesting
that they are likely to be inefficient
providers. In any event, to the extent
such providers can demonstrate that
they are unable to receive fair
compensation under our rate caps, they
would be eligible to seek a waiver as
described below.
66. In short, our revenue estimates are
likely understatements, for the reasons
described below. We also find that
many of the providers’ reported costs
are likely to be higher than efficientlyincurred costs, and this is specifically
the case for the carriers just discussed.
Consequently, we have a high degree of
confidence that our prescribed caps
would allow efficient providers of ICS
to operate profitably.
67. Our revenue imputation likely
underestimates the actual revenues
providers would obtain for four reasons.
First, our analysis does not take into
account the demand stimulation from
lower rates. But there is substantial
record evidence showing that, to the
extent that our caps lower existing rates,
they will increase minutes of use and
raise provider revenues.
68. Second, we impute rates that in
some cases will be lower than the rates
the providers may actually charge. The
resulting revenue underestimate could
PO 00000
Frm 00011
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
79145
be material for six of the providers for
which we impute losses at our
prescribed rate caps, meaning that as a
practical matter they could make up for
any shortfall. All these providers have
jail contracts with ADPs of at least 350,
and some of these providers have a large
number of such contracts. To estimate
each provider’s revenues under the rate
caps we adopt today, we calculate the
revenues the provider would have
earned given the MOU the provider
reported for 2012 and 2013 for debit and
prepaid calls in the three different jail
size categories, 0–349, 350–999, and
1,000+, for prisons, and for collect calls
(so, for example, if a carrier had 1,000
debit MOU in the 0–349 category, we
assume the provider would earn $220 (=
1,000*$0.22)). This approach can
understate revenues because providers
reported contracts according to the sum
of the ADP of the facilities covered
under the contract, but in some cases
providers will charge different rates in
different facilities supplied under the
same contract. In that case, when the
contract has an ADP of 350 or more, but
the provider serves under the contract
jails with an ADP that is lower than the
contract ADP, our estimate will
understate the revenues they would
have earned if our prescribed rates were
applied. For example, a contract with an
ADP of between 350 and 999 that
currently sets different rates for different
facilities might cover three jails, each
with an ADP of 150. In that case, while
we would impute a rate of $0.16 to the
prepaid and debit MOU reported under
that contract, in reality the provider
could be entitled to the $0.22 rate cap
on all those MOU. Similarly, all jails
reported under contracts with an ADP of
1,000 or more were imputed the debit
and prepaid rate of $0.14, but some of
these jails could have ADPs of less than
1,000, and in some cases of less than
350. If the contract specified separate
rates by facility, then the provider could
be entitled to either the $0.16 or the
$0.22 rate in those smaller jails.
69. Third, our analysis also does not
take into account the caps that we
impose on ancillary service charges,
which likely will lead to an increase in
minutes of use. Finally, our analysis
does not take into account the fact that
international calls are not subject to our
rate caps and therefore, such calls will
produce more revenue than reflected.
70. A few providers, including GTL,
Securus and Telmate, contend that our
rate caps are too low and will not allow
them to recover their costs. Others assert
that our rate caps may be too low with
respect to particular facilities. Some
representatives of jail facilities express
concern that the provision of ICS in
E:\FR\FM\18DER2.SGM
18DER2
79146
Federal Register / Vol. 80, No. 243 / Friday, December 18, 2015 / Rules and Regulations
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES2
their facilities may be in jeopardy.
Based on our analysis and the record,
we find these assertions unpersuasive.
Several providers dispute their claims,
noting that GTL, Securus, and Telmate
failed to break out their costs by facility
type, and proposed rate caps well above
their reported average costs over both
prisons and jails. As a result, ‘‘any claim
that the Commission’s draft rates are
demonstrably below carriers’ reported
costs is wholly unsubstantiated and
without merit.’’ Our analysis indicates
that the rate caps we adopt will permit
just, reasonable, and fair compensation.
Moreover, we expect that the reforms
adopted will lead to increased minutes
of use, incentivize increased efficiency,
and permit providers to generate
increased revenues. Thus, we do not
believe that there is a reason for service
to facilities to be in jeopardy but, as
noted below, there is a process for
considering any unique circumstances
that may justify a waiver to ensure fair
compensation.
c. Evidence That the Mandatory Data
Collection Likely Overstates Providers’
Costs
71. In addition to the analysis detailed
above, evidence in the record suggesting
that a number of ICS providers
overstated their costs in response to the
Mandatory Data Collection provides us
with further comfort that the rate caps
adopted today are appropriate and
ensure fair compensation to the
providers.
72. For instance, providers were
directed to file a Description and
Justification (D&J) with their Mandatory
Data Collection response to document
and explain their cost submissions.
Three providers did not submit a D&J to
the Commission. The D&Js received
varied widely in detail and
thoroughness. Five providers
(CenturyLink, GTL, Pay Tel, Securus,
and Telmate) claimed a cost of capital
of 11.25 percent in developing their cost
data submission. (While other providers
did not specify a cost of capital, given
the length of this proceeding and the
fact that the Commission clearly
signaled its focus on setting appropriate
ICS rates, as well as the fact that these
respondents are sophisticated parties,
we think that it is reasonable to assume
that all responding providers included a
cost of capital whether they specified it
or not.) The cost of capital has to be
estimated and their estimate of 11.25
percent might be significantly higher
than the prevailing cost of capital for
companies that provide
telecommunication services. In any
event, none of these companies
submitted evidence as to their costs of
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:49 Dec 17, 2015
Jkt 238001
debt or equity capital or capital
structure, the three components of the
cost of capital, and so have not justified
any cost of capital estimate. In addition,
several providers (Securus, Telmate,
and CenturyLink) included in their
costs financing items as well as interest
expense, which is included in the cost
of capital. This suggests that these
providers, and possibly others, have
over-estimated their capital costs,
potentially double-counting their cost of
debt. The five providers that specifically
reported using 11.25 percent account for
a large portion of the market, and thus
a commensurate weight is reflected in
the weighted average caps that we
calculate. Consequently, in the unlikely
event that a provider omitted its cost of
capital, the omission is unlikely to have
a significant impact on the weighted
average caps. We also note that the
Bureau has recommended to the
Commission that a zone of
reasonableness for the Weighted
Average Cost of Capital (WACC) is
between 7.39 and 8.72 percent.
73. We also find that the manner in
which the data was collected and the
clearly-stated purpose of the data
collection, which occurred in the
context of a Commission effort to set
caps on ICS rates, gave providers every
incentive to represent their ICS costs
fully, and possibly, in some instances,
even to overstate these costs. For
example, one provider noted in its D&J
that it even included in its ICS-related
costs amounts for dues, subscriptions,
entertainment and meals. We question
the appropriateness of including such
costs as ICS-related costs but as noted
below we accept these reported costs
without discounting or manipulating
them. We have observed that at least
one reporting provider did not actually
calculate the percentage of traffic for
each service (debit, prepaid or collect)
represented but rather used the same
percentage for each and merely offered
a ‘‘guess’’ in reporting its 2014 data
projections. This information forces us
to call into question the accuracy of this
provider’s data and how rigorous this
provider was in preparing its Mandatory
Data Collection response. That the
adopted rate caps include such costs, as
well as the costs of international calls
that are not subject to our rate caps,
causes us to conclude that the adopted
caps are generous. An analysis of the
adopted rate caps shows that some
providers will recover more than their
stated costs, while others will recover
less (because the caps are based on
weighted industry averages but, as
explained above, we believe all
PO 00000
Frm 00012
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
providers can more than recover the
efficient costs of ICS supply).
74. Moreover, comments in the record
have also highlighted how the data
likely overstate costs. For example, the
Petitioners’ economist, Coleman
Bazelon, and Pay Tel’s economic
consultant Don Wood identified
problems they observed with the data.
Dr. Bazelon also reported that, based on
an analysis that included information
not included in the provider’s
Mandatory Data Collection submissions,
the reported costs of Securus and GTL
‘‘include many incorrectly calculated
additions such as inappropriately
recoverable financing costs.’’ Dr.
Bazelon reports that, [BEGIN
CONFIDENTIAL] [END
CONFIDENTIAL].
75. After recalculating the providers’
costs, Dr. Bazelon then concludes that
their reported costs should be
discounted by approximately [BEGIN
CONFIDENTIAL] [END
CONFIDENTIAL]. While we do not
discount the costs as recommended by
Dr. Bazelon and, instead, take a more
conservative approach of using the data
at face value, this analysis underscores
that the data submitted likely overstates
costs and, as a result, the rate caps we
adopt today are conservative.
d. Alternative Proposals in the Record
76. Numerous commenters have
submitted rate reform proposals in the
record. The Petitioners, along with
several public interest groups, initially
urged the Commission to adopt a $0.07
per minute rate cap for all interstate
debit, prepaid, and collect calls, with no
per-call charge, and no ancillary fees or
taxes allowed. GTL, Securus, and
Telmate, who describe themselves as
‘‘the primary providers of inmate calling
services . . . in the United States and
represent[ ] 85% of the industry revenue
in 2013,’’ jointly filed a proposal to
comprehensively reform all aspects of
ICS. The Joint Provider Proposal urges
the adoption of rate caps of $0.20 per
minute for debit and prepaid interstate
and intrastate ICS, and $0.24 per minute
for all interstate and intrastate collect
ICS, effective 90 days after adoption of
a final order. The Joint Provider
Proposal does not indicate that it is
based on cost data received in response
to the Mandatory Data Collection. In
addition, the Joint Provider Proposal
was signed by only three of the 14 ICS
providers that responded to the
Mandatory Data Collection. Pay Tel
submitted what it calls an ‘‘Ethical
Proposal,’’ in which it proposes rate
caps of $0.08 per minute for all prisons
regardless of population, $0.26 per
minute for jails with 1–349 ADP, and
E:\FR\FM\18DER2.SGM
18DER2
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 80, No. 243 / Friday, December 18, 2015 / Rules and Regulations
$0.22 per minute for jails with 350 plus
ADP. The Commission sought comment
on these proposals in the Second
FNPRM.
77. In response to the Second FNPRM,
Petitioners submitted another reform
proposal. The Petitioners propose a rate
of $0.08/minute for prepaid and debit
calls and $0.10/minute for collect calls
from all prisons and jails with over 350
beds. Petitioners propose a rate of $0.18/
minute for prepaid and debit calls and
$0.20/minute for collect for facilities
with fewer than 350 beds. Petitioners
suggest that the Commission adopt these
tiered rates to account for higher churn
rates, increased non-revenue calls, and
higher bad debt issues experienced in
smaller facilities. In its comments to the
Second FNPRM, PPI supports a cap of
$0.05 to $0.07 per minute.
78. Several commenters submitted
economic justifications for their rate
proposals, each of which relied on a
slightly different subset of the data in
the Mandatory Data Collection. For the
reasons described below, the
Commission declines to adopt any of
these proposals.
79. After comments were received in
response to the Second FNPRM, Pay Tel
filed an additional proposal based on its
economic consultant’s analysis of the
data filed in response to the Mandatory
Data Collection. The company proposes
tiered per-minute rate caps, for all call
types, plus institution cost recovery
amounts to be added to those caps. The
rates (rate cap plus additional facility
cost recovery) would range from $0.10/
min for prisons to $0.29/min for jails of
0–349 inmates. Specifically, Pay Tel’s
economic consultant, Don Wood,
excluded from his analysis, and
subsequent proposed rate caps, the data
from ATN, Encartele, and Protocall
because he did not receive data from
those providers, and from Combined
Public Communications, Custom
Teleconnect and Correct Solutions,
because he deemed them ‘‘unreliable for
the purpose at hand.’’ Mr. Wood then
observed that the remaining eight
reporting ICS providers’ data included
no description of how their cost studies
were performed, and stated that ‘‘a
number of the studies are decidedly
imperfect, and more complete
documentation would certainly be
desirable.’’ Regardless, Mr. Wood
suggested that ‘‘key results of these
studies should be relied upon by the
Commission when making any
decisions regarding the level and
structure of ICS costs.’’ We conclude
that our approach is more appropriate
because it includes data from all
providers, rather than excluding six of
the fourteen reporting providers’ data.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:49 Dec 17, 2015
Jkt 238001
This approach is less reliable than our
rate caps because of its selective nature.
While we agree that the data are not
perfect, we do not believe it is
appropriate to ignore the filed data and
we find Mr. Wood’s rationale for
excluding certain providers’ data
unpersuasive without additional
justification. As such, the rate caps
adopted herein are derived from all data
filed in the record.
80. In comments to the Second
FNPRM, the Wright Petitioners’
economist, Coleman Bazelon, identified
problems he observed with the data
received in response to the Mandatory
Data Collection. For example, Dr.
Bazelon identified inconsistencies in
how providers categorized and allocated
costs. Dr. Bazelon then discussed the
rate caps that the Wright Petitioners’
proposed in their comments. These rate
caps were based on Securus’ and GTL’s
average cost data, which Dr. Bazelon
then discounted because of concerns
regarding Securus’ cost-reporting
methodology. As noted above, Dr.
Bazelon found errors in Securus’ and
GTL’s submissions, which led them to
likely overstate their reported costs.
After adjusting for these errors, the
Wright Petitioners suggest that an
appropriate rate cap for service to prison
facilities should be $0.08/minute for
debit/prepaid calling and $0.10/minute
for collect calling.
81. We appreciate Dr. Bazelon’s
analysis highlighting that the data are
likely to be overstated, but we do not
believe it is appropriate for our
purposes. Dr. Bazelon’s analysis
suggests that one provider may have
overstated its costs by some significant
amount. We find Dr. Bazelon’s analysis
of the submitted data troubling and
believe that his conclusions, if true,
might support discounting cost data
from certain providers. (We note,
however, that our filing instructions did
not specify in detail how providers
should account for the data that Dr.
Bazelon discussed, although we
required providers to identify and
explain all costs in the accompanying
Description and Justification. The lack
of specific instruction regarding the
method of cost reporting should not
have been interpreted as license to
manipulate or over-report cost data, and
the reference to the penalty for willful
false statements should have made that
evident.) While we are concerned that
the analysis from Dr. Bazelon suggests
that costs were overstated, we do not
believe it is appropriate to adopt a rate
cap based on discounting a single
provider’s costs when we have data
from 13 other providers. In addition, we
determine above that we should not
PO 00000
Frm 00013
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
79147
manipulate the data but more
conservatively accept the providers’
costs as filed to avoid potentially
arbitrary means of working with the
data.
82. Alabama Public Service
Commission Utility Services Division
Director Darrell Baker likewise reviewed
the data. His proposal includes four
tiers each for prisons and jails, based on
inmate population, with both rate caps
and additional facility cost-recovery
amounts, yielding rates ranging from
$0.12/min (prisons with more than
19,999 inmates) to $0.25/min (jails of
less than 100 inmates). In support of his
proposal for prison rates, Mr. Baker
relied on cost data from only seven of
the reporting 14 providers. He excluded
from his rate cap and cost-recovery
calculations the seven smallest
reporting providers, on the basis ‘‘that
the . . . [remaining] providers serve the
overwhelming majority of jails and
prisons and that . . . an analysis of their
data should provide accurate and
reliable results that are applicable across
the entire industry.’’ In support of his
proposal for jail rates, Mr. Baker relied
on data from only six of the reporting
providers, excluding one of the seven
remaining providers’ data because that
‘‘[o]ne provider’s cost per MOU deviates
substantially from the cost per MOU of
other providers.’’ We find Mr. Baker’s
approach problematic because it
eliminated the higher cost data in the
record. Put another way, the seven
smallest providers submitted what were
among the highest reported costs of
providing ICS and the other excluded
provider by process of elimination must
be a larger provider that is responsible
for a more-significant portion of ICS
minutes of use. Additionally, Mr. Baker
appears to have given no consideration
to potential justifications, if any, for that
provider’s higher costs. We are unable,
on the record before us, to exclude
providers’ reported data in calculating
the appropriate rate caps.
83. The comments in the record
largely agree that the data are
problematic but disagree on the reasons
why and the overall effect on the
reported data. Each analysis described
above is based on a different data set
and criticizes the data for slightly
different reasons. We take seriously the
concerns that the commenters have
raised about inconsistencies in the data,
and for at least some of the reasons
described above, conclude that the
reported data likely overstates the
providers’ actual costs. But, as
explained herein, we are unable to agree
with and do not adopt any of the
commenters’ choices about which data
to exclude or discount.
E:\FR\FM\18DER2.SGM
18DER2
79148
Federal Register / Vol. 80, No. 243 / Friday, December 18, 2015 / Rules and Regulations
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES2
e. Rate Caps for Collect Calls
84. In this section, we conclude that
it is appropriate to put in place a
temporary, distinct rate structure for
collect calls, with a two-year phase
down after which rate caps for collect
calls will be the same as those of debit
and prepaid calls.
85. In the 2013 Order, the
Commission established a rate cap for
interstate debit and prepaid calling and
a separate rate cap for interstate collect
calling. The interim interstate collect
calling rate cap was $0.25. In setting this
separate rate cap, the Commission
recognized that, based on the data
available at the time, collect calling can
be more expensive for ICS providers to
offer than debit and prepaid calling. The
Commission encouraged facilities to
move away from collect calling, noting
that the use of prepaid calling helps
called parties to better manage their
budgets for ICS, thus making end-user
costs for maintaining contact more
predictable. The Commission also noted
that debit and prepaid calling address
the problem of call blocking associated
with collect calling by enabling service
providers to obtain payment for calls up
front, thus eliminating the risk of
nonpayment.
86. In the Second FNPRM, the
Commission sought comment on
retaining the differentials between
debit/prepaid and collect calling. The
Commission noted that data received
from the Mandatory Data Collection
suggest that collect calling costs are
higher than costs for prepaid and debit
calls, and that collect calling accounted
for less than nine percent of revenue
producing minutes in the data
collection in 2013. Commenters suggest
that collect calling is more costly to
provide because of bad debt, billing
costs, uncollectible debts and issues
related to collection of non-payment.
For example, some commenters still
assert that the Commission should
adopt a higher rate cap for collect
calling, largely because of the higher
costs associated with collect call
service. The Commission, along with
several commenters, has noted that use
of collect calling in correctional
facilities has dropped significantly in
recent years. Data received in response
to the Mandatory Data Collection
confirm this decline. Between 2012 and
2014, collect-calling minutes of use
decreased over 50 percent, from 15 to 7
percent of minutes of use. CenturyLink
recently told the Commission that ‘‘that
traditional collect calling represents a
small and declining percentage of
inmate calls.’’
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:49 Dec 17, 2015
Jkt 238001
87. Based on our analysis of the
record, including data submitted in
response to the Mandatory Data
Collection, we predict that collect
calling usage will continue to decrease
in the future. We do not want to include
high collect calling costs in debit and
prepaid rate tiers because that would
compel the majority of ICS end users
that do not use collect calling to
subsidize such calls. In light of that
concern, and because we continue to
encourage correctional institutions to
move away from collect calling, as the
Commission did in the 2013 Order, we
adopt a separate rate cap tier for collect
calling. This separate tier is consistent
with the Commission’s prior actions in
adopting a separate collect calling rate
tier based on data indicating that collect
calls were more expensive than other
types of ICS calls. Since the adoption of
our interim rate caps, only one provider
has been granted a waiver based on an
assertion of unreasonable or
unsustainable rate caps, further
supporting the reasonableness of the
rate of the interim collect calling rate
caps.
88. We adopt a collect calling rate cap
based on the cost data received in
response to the Mandatory Data
Collection, as well as a two-year stepdown transitional period, as follows.
First, we adopt a collect calling rate of
$0.49/per minute for all jails and $0.14
for all prisons until July 1, 2017.
Beginning July 1, 2017, we adopt a rate
of $0.36/per minute for jails of 0–349
ADP, $0.33/per minute for jails of 349–
999 ADP, and $0.32/per minute for jails
of 1,000 or greater ADP, and $0.14/per
minute for all prisons. This rate is
halfway between the initial rate and the
rates that are adopted in this Order for
debit and prepaid calling. Finally,
effective July 1, 2018 and beyond, we
adopt a collect calling rate of $0.22/per
minute for jails of 0–349 ADP, $0.16/per
minute for jails with 359–999 ADP, and
$0.14/per minute for jails of 1,000 or
greater ADP, and $0.11/per minute for
all prisons, in order to arrive at rates
that are identical to those adopted in
this Order for jails and prisons and the
respective tiers therein.
89. We conclude that these separate
tiers for collect calling rates will phase
out after a two-year transition period.
This two-year framework is justified by
the data filed in response to the
Mandatory Data Collection, showing
that collect calling volume is decreasing
and will most likely be at a nominal
level in two years. By adopting a twoyear glide path, the rates ICS providers
are permitted to charge phase down
over time, with certainty and sufficient
time to adapt to a changed landscape
PO 00000
Frm 00014
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
that includes reduced use of collect
calling overall. We find that this
transitional approach will be
administratively efficient for both
providers and the Commission, as it
involves a straightforward two-year
step-down process and reflects our
expectation that providers will gain
efficiencies in their contracts and collect
calling, and that they will thus more
easily adjust to the lower rate caps
adopted for debit and prepaid calling.
90. Moreover, the record supports a
uniform rate for collect calls. Indeed,
several commenters no longer support a
separate rate cap for collect calling,
indicating that collect calling costs may
not, in fact, differ significantly from
debit or prepaid calling costs, or that
collect calling accounts for a relatively
small portion of calls. The record
indicates that this is because
correctional institutions favor debit or
prepaid calling over collect calling. For
example, when the Commission
adopted the 2013 Order, evidence in the
record indicated that collect calling was
the only ICS option offered in four states
and now the record indicates that
collect calling is the only ICS option in
one state. As the Commission has stated
previously, we encourage providers and
facilities to move away from collect
calling for the many efficiencies and
cost savings that other types of calling
offer. Finally, we find that a two-year
transition will allow the Bureau to
monitor collect calling and address any
potential traffic arbitrage issue that
might occur if providers shift calling
patterns to take advantage of the higher
collect calling rate caps.
91. We acknowledge that the collect
calling rate caps will be higher in year
one than several of the collect calling
caps proposed in the record. We expect
that these caps will serve as backstops,
not a target for providers, as efficiencies
are gained by providers, and contracts
are changed, or new contracts are
entered into between parties. As
discussed above, we expect that the
trend towards declining collect calling
volume will continue, and the adopted
rate caps may be further modified in
response to further data received as part
of the MDC adopted herein.
92. We delegate to the Bureau the
authority to seek comment on the
possibility of adjusting the adopted
collect calling rate cap if necessary to
address any gaming issues that may
arise prior to completion of the phasedown. As part of the annual reporting
and certification requirement adopted
herein, the Bureau will be monitoring
collect call volume in order to review
trends and to ensure that gaming does
not occur. As discussed below, the
E:\FR\FM\18DER2.SGM
18DER2
Federal Register / Vol. 80, No. 243 / Friday, December 18, 2015 / Rules and Regulations
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES2
Commission also plans to collect rate
data, including data about collect
calling rates that will further inform this
review.
f. Cost-Benefit Analysis
93. In adopting these rate caps, we
have carefully considered each proposal
or suggestion from the extensive
comments in the record and weighed its
potential benefit against any potential
burden it may impose, bearing in mind
our statutory mandate that ICS rates
must be just, reasonable, and fair,
maximizing the public benefit from any
proposal we adopt. We find, on balance,
that the benefits of our rate caps
outweigh any potential burden that may
be imposed. For example, regular family
contact not only benefits the public
broadly by reducing crime, lessening the
need for additional correctional
facilities and cutting overall costs to
society, but also likely has a positive
effect on the welfare of inmates’
children. Ensuring just and reasonable
ICS rates will foster regular contact
between inmates and families, reduce
the economic burden on ICS end users,
support more cost-effective
communication between inmates and
their counsel, and produce cost savings
for the justice system.
94. Additionally, as the Commission
discussed in the 2012 NPRM, studies
show that regular contact with family
reduces inmate recidivism. Children
who continue to stay in touch with their
parent in prison exhibit fewer
disruptive and anxious behaviors. Yet,
according to one study, only 38 percent
of inmates reported ‘‘at least’’ monthly
phone calls with their children. Real
telephone contact between inmates and
their loved ones at high rates places a
heavy burden on inmates’ families
because families typically bear the
burden of paying for the calls. The
Government Accountability Office
(GAO) has twice recognized the
conclusions of Federal Bureau of
Prisons officials that contact with family
‘‘aids an inmate’s success when
returning to the community’’ and thus
lowers recidivism. Moreover, the GAO
has found that ‘‘crowded visiting rooms
make it more difficult for inmates to
visit with their families’’ and that ‘‘[t]he
infrastructure of the facility may not
support the increase in visitors as a
result of the growth in the prison
population.’’
95. As discussed above, there is little
dispute that the ICS market is
experiencing market failure. Numerous
commenters have expressed as much.
Various parties encourage the
Commission to reform rates within
inmate calling, and some offer specific
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:49 Dec 17, 2015
Jkt 238001
reform proposals. Reforms are necessary
to ensure that the benefits discussed
above, which are in the public interest,
will be realized.
96. The Order recognizes, however,
that imposing rate caps may impose
burdens on some providers. We have
taken steps to minimize burdens on
providers. As discussed below, we
allow a 90-day transition period for the
rate caps adopted in this Order to take
effect for prisons and six months for the
applicable rate caps to take effect in
jails. We find that this length of time
adequately balances the pressing need
for reform while affording ICS providers
and facilities sufficient time to prepare
for the new rates. Further, our rate caps
are designed to ensure that efficient
providers will recover all legitimate
costs of providing ICS, including a
reasonable return, and, to the extent a
provider can demonstrate special
circumstances, it may seek relief from
our rules in the form of a waiver.
Specifically, the Commission will
consider requests from a provider
arguing that particular facts, when
considered in the context of the totality
of the relevant circumstances, deprive
the provider of fair compensation or
have a substantial and deleterious effect
on competition in the ICS market.
97. Additionally, the rate caps
adopted in the Order include fewer tiers
than the number of tiers used in the data
requested in our Mandatory Data
Collection. The Commission collected
data, for example, on the costs of
serving jail facilities with 0–99 ADP, a
grouping comprising less than 10
percent of the inmate population, but
we did not adopt that as a rate tier,
thereby mitigating any administrative
burden on providers of adding a
separate rate tier for this comparatively
small grouping. The rate caps we adopt
today respond to commenter concerns
regarding potential confusion and
burden caused by multiple rates. We
also adopt a single rate cap for prisons,
which should minimize the burden on
providers that serve prisons. Finally, we
disagree with those commenters who
assert that adopting a tiered rate
structure would be unduly burdensome
and difficult for the Commission to
administer and for ICS providers and
correctional officers to implement. We
find these allegations unsupported and
commenters provide no persuasive
evidence that our rate tiers would be
more difficult for them to administer
than the current approaches.
PO 00000
Frm 00015
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
79149
4. Rejection of Certain Types of Charges
a. No Per-Call or Per-Connection
Charges
98. Background. Per-call or perconnection charges are one-time fees
often charged to ICS users at call
initiation. In the 2013 Order, the
Commission noted problems with percall charges, ‘‘potentially rendering such
charges unjust, unreasonable and
unfair.’’ Problems included calls
dropped ‘‘without regard to whether
there is a potential security or technical
issue, and a per-call charge . . .
imposed on the initial call and each
successive call.’’ The Commission
expressed ‘‘serious concerns about such
charges’’ and sought comment about the
risks of such charges, but did not ban
them.
99. In the Second FNPRM, the
Commission sought additional comment
about such charges. First, the
Commission asked if it should consider
per-call or per-connection charges to be
part of the ICS rate and ‘‘therefore
subject to the section 276 mandate to
ensure fair compensation.’’ Second, the
Commission asked, in the alternative, if
it should consider per-call or perconnection fees more analogous to the
ancillary fees discussed in section
276(d). The Commission asked if there
are ‘‘instances in which the correctional
facility or some other third party
assesses a per-call or per-connection
fee,’’ and, if so, the Commission sought
comment on its authority to ban such
charges. Finally, the Commission sought
comment on whether the elimination of
per-call charges would allow for just
and reasonable interstate and intrastate
ICS rates and fair compensation for ICS
providers, on ‘‘transitions’’ away from
such charges, and on its legal authority
to act on per-call or per-connection
charges.
100. We received limited comment in
the record, but all supported the
elimination of per-call or perconnection fees. For example, HRDC
supports the ‘‘elimination of per-call
charges’’ for existing contracts. Legal
Services for Prisoners with Children
asserts that ‘‘per-call’’ or connection fees
are ‘‘unreasonably high’’ and that the
Commission ‘‘should ban these charges’’
or, ‘‘at the very least,’’ should introduce
a ‘‘dropped call’’ provision that
‘‘prohibits ICS providers from charging
multiple times for a call that has been
reinitiated within a few minutes.’’ Pay
Tel notes that if the Commission adopts
‘‘any rate cap regime—including Pay
Tel’s Proposal—that does not allow
providers to charge end users an upfront
surcharge or per-call surcharge, it will
E:\FR\FM\18DER2.SGM
18DER2
79150
Federal Register / Vol. 80, No. 243 / Friday, December 18, 2015 / Rules and Regulations
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES2
successfully eliminate the problem of
premature disconnection of calls.’’
101. Discussion. We disallow the use
of per-call or per-connection charges
pursuant to our legal authority to ensure
just, reasonable, and fair ICS rates. No
evidence in the record supports a
conclusion that these charges are a
necessary part of cost recovery for ICS
calls. Indeed, no commenters indicated
that these fees are tied to a cost that
providers incur in initiating a call.
Providers did not break out per-call or
per-connection costs when they filed
their per-minute costs in response to the
Mandatory Data Collection, indicating
that any costs incurred on a per-call
basis were included in their per-minute
cost calculations. Allowing providers to
recover such charges on top of the perminute rates we adopt in this Order
would therefore risk allowing double
recovery. Additionally, these fees
appear to be less prevalent than they
once were. Recent provider-drafted
reform proposals in the record do not
include per-call or per-connection
charges, and many recently-adopted ICS
contracts likewise do not include these
fees. All of these factors indicate to us
a trend away from the inclusion of such
fees. Finally, we agree with the
Commission’s earlier finding in the
2013 Order that allowing such fees may
encourage providers to charge end users
for dropped calls, which could lead to
the ‘‘assessment of multiple per-call
charges for what was, in effect, a single
conversation,’’ which has no place in a
framework for just, reasonable, and fair
compensation. We find that disallowing
such fees is in the public interest
because it will decrease the cost to end
users for shorter ICS calls and allow
more contact between inmates and their
loved ones.
b. No Flat-Rate Calling
102. Background. In the 2013 Order
the Commission noted that commenters
raised issues regarding per-call charges
that may be unjust, unreasonable, and
unfair; callers are often charged more
during a single conversation when calls
are dropped, which the record reveals
can be a frequent occurrence, thus
resulting in multiple calls for a single
conversation, each subject to a separate
flat-rate charge. The Commission stated
that ‘‘a rate will be considered
consistent with our rate cap for a 15minute conversation if it does not
exceed $3.75 for a 15-minute call using
collect calling, or $3.15 for a 15-minute
call using debit, prepaid, or prepaid
collect calling.’’ Rule 64.6030 mirrors
this language and was intended to
illustrate that the rate for a five-minute
collect call must be capped at $1.25 and
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:49 Dec 17, 2015
Jkt 238001
the rate for a five-minute debit or
prepaid ICS call must be capped at
$1.05, while a 30-minute collect call
could cost consumers no more than
$7.50 and a 30-minute debit or prepaid
ICS call no more than $6.30.
103. Discussion. Subsequent to the
2013 Order, Securus sought additional
guidance on this issue, asking whether
providers were allowed to impose a flat
rate based on the interim rate caps for
a 15-minute call regardless of actual call
duration. That is, it wished to know if
it could charge a flat fee of $3.75 for a
collect call of any duration up to 15
minutes. The Commission sought
comment on Securus’ question, as well
as on whether it should revise the
existing rules to prohibit flat-rate
charges or to develop new rules
prohibiting flat-rated charges.
104. The record reflects minimal
support for this practice. The Alabama
PSC opposes Securus’ proposed
clarification, stating that ‘‘flat-rate
pricing allows providers to maximize
call revenues and to dictate phone usage
to the end users.’’ It further asserts that
flat-rate calling increases complaints
related to dropped calls and penalizes
inmates that want to make shorter calls.
Several commenters suggest that ICS
providers will benefit from a ban on flatrate calls because it will lower their
costs related to consumer complaints
and bill adjustments. HRDC notes that
the proposed flat rates ‘‘only fall within
the rate caps when a full 15-minute call
is actually completed’’ and argues that
‘‘this practice does not reflect the spirit’’
of the Commission’s 2013 Order. Pay
Tel asserts that ‘‘numerous ICS
providers have taken advantage of this
language and vague guidance since
release of the ICS Order and are
charging end users a flat rate of $3.15 or
$3.75 per call, even if the call is
disconnected prior to expiration of
fifteen minutes,’’ which it asserts is ‘‘an
abuse of the intent of the Commission’s
rules.’’
105. We prohibit the imposition of
flat-rate calling. There is minimal record
support for such charges, which
penalize those who make shorter calls
(the record indicates that ICS calls last
typically less than 15 minutes). If an
end user is charged for a 15-minute call
but the duration of that call is less than
15 minutes, the price for that call is
disproportionately high. We also agree
with those commenters who assert that
allowing providers to charge a flat rate
based on a 15-minute call does not
comport with our requirement to make
ICS rates just, reasonable, and fair. As
such, we ban flat-rate calling rate plans.
PO 00000
Frm 00016
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
5. Legal Authority for Intrastate and
Interstate Rate Caps
106. Background. In the 2013 FNPRM,
the Commission tentatively concluded
that section 276 affords it broad
authority to reform intrastate ICS rates
and practices that deny fair
compensation, as well as to preempt
inconsistent state requirements. The
Commission sought comment on these
tentative conclusions. Multiple
commenters supported the
Commission’s tentative conclusion that
it has jurisdiction over intrastate as well
as interstate ICS rates. These
commenters argue that section 276
provides the Commission with clear
jurisdiction, and that it must regulate
intrastate rates to ensure comprehensive
ICS reform. After examining the record,
we affirm the tentative conclusion that
intrastate ICS rates are well within the
Commission’s jurisdiction for the
reasons described below.
107. Our authority to ensure the
reasonableness of rates and practices for
interstate ICS is not in dispute. Under
section 201(b) of the Communications
Act, the FCC is empowered to
‘‘prescribe such rules and regulations as
may be necessary’’ to ensure that ‘‘[a]ll
charges [and] practices . . . for and in
connection with [interstate]
communication service’’ by wire or
radio are ‘‘just and reasonable.’’ Section
276 directs the Commission to
‘‘establish a per call compensation plan
to ensure that all payphone service
providers’’—which the statute defines to
include providers of ICS—‘‘are fairly
compensated for each and every
completed intrastate and interstate
call.’’ (The Commission has previously
found that the term ‘‘fairly
compensated’’ permits a range of
compensation rates that could be
considered fair, but that the interests of
both the payphone service providers
and the parties paying the compensation
must be taken into account.) We find
that these statutory sections provide the
Commission with the authority to
regulate interstate ICS rates and
practices, including the use of per-call
or per-connection fees as well as flatrate calling.
108. Legal Authority to Reform
Intrastate Rates. The Commission’s
authority over intrastate
telecommunications is, except as
otherwise provided by Congress,
generally limited by section 2(b) of the
Act, which states that ‘‘nothing in this
Act shall . . . give the Commission
jurisdiction with respect to . . .
intrastate communication service by
wire or radio.’’ As the Supreme Court
has held, however, section 2(b) has no
E:\FR\FM\18DER2.SGM
18DER2
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 80, No. 243 / Friday, December 18, 2015 / Rules and Regulations
effect where the Communications Act,
by its terms, unambiguously applies to
intrastate services. We conclude that
such is the case here.
109. Under section 276 of the
Communications Act, the Commission
is charged with implementing
Congress’s directive ‘‘that all payphone
service providers [be] fairly
compensated for each and every
completed intrastate and interstate
call.’’ Section 276 contains several
express references both to ICS and
intrastate calling, making it clear that
the Commission has the authority to
regulate intrastate ICS calling. For
example, section 276 requires the
Commission to broadly craft regulations
to ‘‘promote the widespread
development of payphone services for
the benefit of the general public’’
including, notably, ‘‘the provision of
inmate telephone service in correctional
institutions, and any ancillary services.’’
In addition to this general grant of
jurisdiction, section 276 includes a
mandate to ‘‘establish a per call
compensation plan to ensure that all
payphone service providers are fairly
compensated for each and every
completed intrastate and interstate call
using their payphone.’’ Section 276 also
expressly directs the Commission to
‘‘discontinue the intrastate and
interstate carrier access charge
payphone service elements. . .and all
intrastate and interstate payphone
subsidies.’’ In addition, section 276
explicitly grants the Commission
authority to preempt state requirements
to the extent they are inconsistent with
FCC regulations.
110. Furthermore, significant judicial
precedent supports the Commission’s
authority to regulate intrastate ICS. In
Illinois Public Telecommunications
Association, the U.S. Court of Appeals
for the D.C. Circuit found that the Act’s
requirement that ‘‘all payphone service
providers are fairly compensated’’
provides the FCC with ‘‘authority to set
local coin call rates’’—which included
intrastate service rates. Additionally, in
New England Public Comm’ns Council,
Inc. v. FCC, the same court found that
‘‘section 276 unambiguously and
straightforwardly authorizes the
Commission to regulate . . . intrastate
payphone line rates.’’ Therefore, we
conclude that both section 276 and the
associated case law give the
Commission the authority to regulate
ICS provider compensation for intrastate
calls, including the rates ICS providers
charge end users, per-call or perconnection charges, and flat-rate
charges.
111. We find arguments that the
Commission lacks the authority to
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:49 Dec 17, 2015
Jkt 238001
regulate intrastate ICS unpersuasive. For
example, we disagree with commenters
who argue that section 276 is limited to
prohibiting discrimination by Bell
operating companies (BOCs). While
section 276(a) includes provisions
specifically prohibiting discrimination
by BOCs, we do not believe Congress
intended for that subsection to limit the
scope of the remaining provisions of
section 276. For example, section
276(b)(1) expressly mandates that the
Commission adopt regulations
addressing five specific subjects related
to payphone services; only two of those
subjects—clauses (C) and (D)—relate to
preventing BOC discrimination.
112. In addition, although section
276(a) refers to Bell operating
companies, and applies only to the
BOCs, section 276(b) refers more
broadly to ‘‘payphone service
providers.’’ If Congress had intended for
the regulations prescribed under section
276(b) to be limited to the narrow
purpose of effectuating the
nondiscrimination goals set forth in
section 276(a), it easily could have made
that clear. Instead, Congress made clear
that it was conferring a broader mandate
in section 276(b), stating that: ‘‘[i]n
order to promote competition among
payphone service providers and to
promote the widespread deployment of
payphone services . . . , the
Commission shall take all actions
necessary . . . to prescribe regulations
that . . . [inter alia] ensure that all
payphone service providers are fairly
compensated for each and every
completed intrastate and interstate call
using their payphone[s] . . . .’’
113. We also disagree with
commenters who argue that the
Commission has never determined that
section 276 extends to intrastate rates or
that section 276 applies only to ‘‘local
calls made from a payphone and paid
with coins.’’ Section 276 does not
specify that compensation is only for
calls paid by coin but rather ‘‘each and
every’’ call. Indeed, the very
Commission order under review in
Illinois Public Telecommunications held
that the Commission had the authority
to regulate intrastate payphone rates and
preempt state regulation of intrastate
rates. Therefore, the Commission’s
position regarding its authority over
intrastate rates under section 276 has
remained consistent.
114. Rate Caps are Just, Reasonable
and Fair. As noted above, we have
accepted the data submitted by
providers in response to the Mandatory
Data Collection as reported even though
there is evidence that they are
overstated. As a result, we believe our
rate caps are conservative and include
PO 00000
Frm 00017
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
79151
sufficiently generous margins to allow
providers to earn a profit. More
generally, it is well-established that
rates can be lawful if they fall within a
zone of reasonableness, and hence a
particular state’s cap might be lower
than our caps and still fall within that
zone. The rate caps we adopt today are
intended both to ensure that ICS rates
are ‘‘just and reasonable’’ and do not
take unfair advantage of inmates, their
families, or providers consistent with
the ‘‘fair compensation’’ mandate of
section 276.
115. The Commission has broad
discretion in establishing just and
reasonable rates, as long as it articulates
a rational basis for its decisions and as
long as the result is not confiscatory. As
the Supreme Court has explained in
construing the similar ‘‘just and
reasonable rates’’ provision of the
Natural Gas Act, ‘‘the Commission is not
required by the Constitution or the
Natural Gas Act to adopt as just and
reasonable any particular rate level;
rather, courts are without authority to
set aside any rate selected by the
Commission which is within a ‘zone of
reasonableness.’’’ Section 276(b) charges
us with ensuring that ‘‘all payphone
service providers [be] fairly
compensated.’’ This provision must be
read in conjunction with our obligation
under section 201(b) to ensure that
charges and practices be just and
reasonable. Neither section 276(b) nor
201(b) require us to allow for recovery
of costs that are not just, reasonable and
fair.
116. We recognize that some ICS
providers may see their profits decrease
because the adopted caps are below the
costs they reported to us under the
Mandatory Data Collection (assuming
that MOU stay constant). The
Commission has broad authority to set
rate caps to apply to a particular service
and does not have to set providerspecific rates that embody a rate of
return for each individual provider.
Indeed, as at least one provider has
explained in this proceeding, courts
have recognized that the use of
industry-wide average cost data to set
rates is not arbitrary, and therefore
agencies may use composite industry
data or other averaging methods to set
rates. We therefore find that the rates we
adopt today are reasonable for the
reasons provided above and will allow
economically efficient—possibly all—
providers to recover their costs that are
reasonably and directly attributable to
ICS. The costs reported by the providers
that are above our rate caps represent
significant outliers, suggesting that their
reporting methods may have varied
from those of other providers or that
E:\FR\FM\18DER2.SGM
18DER2
79152
Federal Register / Vol. 80, No. 243 / Friday, December 18, 2015 / Rules and Regulations
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES2
they may be less efficient than their
peers. Indeed, encouraging efficiency
will lead to lower rates, which will both
benefit end users as well as increase
calling demand, thus furthering the dual
goals of section 276 ‘‘to promote
competition among payphone service
providers’’ and encourage the
‘‘widespread deployment of payphone
services to the benefit of the public.’’
and state regulators, such as the
Alabama PSC. This broad support from
practically every type of interested party
underscores the reasonableness of our
approach. We will continue to monitor
the market and will take appropriate
action if we find that, notwithstanding
our rate caps, site commissions are
somehow driving ICS rates to levels that
are unjust, unreasonable, or unfair.
B. Payments to Correctional Institutions
117. The record indicates that, in
many cases, ICS bids are predicated on
the winning providers’ willingness to
share part of its ICS revenues with the
correctional facility. These payments,
commonly referred to as ‘‘site
commissions,’’ may take the form of
monetary payments, in-kind payments,
exchanges, or allowances. In this Order,
we define the term ‘‘site commission’’
broadly, to encompass any form of
monetary payment, in-kind payment
requirement, gift, exchange of services
or goods, fee, technology allowance,
product or the like.
118. After carefully considering the
evidence in the record, we affirm our
previous finding that site commissions
do not constitute a legitimate cost to the
providers of providing ICS.
Accordingly, we do not include site
commission payments in the cost data
we use in setting the rate caps
established in this Order. We conclude
that we do not need to prohibit site
commissions in order to ensure that
interstate rates for ICS are fair, just, and
reasonable and that intrastate rates are
fair. We reiterate, however, that site
commissions have been a significant
driver of rates and that ICS rates have
dropped dramatically in states that have
eliminated site commissions. We
therefore encourage other states and
correctional facilities to curtail or
prohibit such payments as part of an
effort to further ensure that inmates and
their families have access to ICS at
affordable rates.
119. We recognize that some states
have adopted reasonable rates that
include a margin sufficient to allow
providers to pay site commissions, thus
demonstrating that it is possible to have
rates that are consistent with our rate
caps but still allow for the payment of
site commissions. The decision to
establish fair and reasonable rate caps
for ICS and leave providers to decide
whether to pay site commissions—and
if so, how much to pay—is supported by
a broad cross-section of commenters,
including consumer advocates, such as
the Wright Petitioners; ICS providers,
such as CenturyLink, NCIC and
ICSolutions; representatives of
correctional facilities, such as Praeses;
1. Background
120. In the 2002 Order, the
Commission concluded that, consistent
with prior precedent, site commissions
ICS providers paid to inmate facilities
were not a cost of providing payphone
service, ‘‘but represent an
apportionment of profits between the
facility owners and the providers of
[ICS].’’ In the 2012 NPRM, the
Commission sought comment on its
longstanding conclusion that site
commissions are not a cost of providing
ICS, and additional comment and data
on site commissions and their impact on
ICS rates.
121. In the subsequent 2013 Order,
the Commission affirmed the previous
determination that site commissions
‘‘are not costs that are reasonably and
directly related to the provision of ICS’’
and determined that site commissions
were ‘‘a significant factor contributing to
high [ICS] rates.’’ The Commission
concluded that, ‘‘under the Act, [site]
commission payments are not costs that
can be recovered through interstate ICS
rates.’’ The Commission noted,
however, the possibility that
correctional facilities may incur costs in
making ICS available to inmates and
sought comment on whether there were
any such costs that should be
compensable through ICS rates.
122. In the Second FNPRM, the
Commission sought additional comment
on potential reforms to site commissions
and its legal authority to ‘‘restrict the
payment of site commissions in the ICS
context pursuant to sections 276 and
201(b) of the Act.’’ As the Commission
explained, site commissions ‘‘distort[]
the ICS marketplace’’ by creating
incentives for the facilities to select
providers that pay the highest site
commissions, even if those providers do
not offer the best service or lowest rates.
The Commission cited responses to the
Mandatory Data Collection showing that
ICS providers paid over $460 million in
site commissions in 2013 alone. Press
reports have cited even higher figures.
These payments represent a significant
portion of total ICS revenues. Indeed, as
the Commission has noted, site
commissions can amount to as much as
96 percent of gross ICS revenues. The
Commission, therefore, sought comment
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:49 Dec 17, 2015
Jkt 238001
PO 00000
Frm 00018
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
on whether it should prohibit all site
commission payments for interstate and
intrastate ICS. The Commission also
sought comment on whether
correctional institutions incur any costs
in the provision of ICS, and requested
data demonstrating that any costs that
facilities bear are ‘‘directly related to the
provision of ICS.’’ To the extent that
correctional facilities were found to
incur costs ‘‘reasonably and directly
related to making ICS available,’’ the
Commission sought comment on
whether recovery of those costs should
be ‘‘built into any per-minute ICS rate
caps.’’
2. Discussion
123. Although we do not prohibit
providers from paying site commissions,
we do not consider the cost of any such
payments in setting our rate caps.
(Regardless of whether site commission
payments constitute an ‘‘appointment of
profits’’ or a cost to the provider, they
cannot be recovered through ICS rates
unless they are ‘‘reasonably and directly
related to the provision of ICS.)
Evidence submitted in response to the
Second FNPRM reinforces the
Commission’s conclusion that the site
commissions ICS providers pay to some
correctional facilities are not reasonably
related to the provision of ICS and
should not be considered in
determining fair compensation for ICS
calls. HRDC, for example, describes site
commissions as ‘‘legal bribes to induce
correctional agencies to provide ICS
providers with lucrative monopoly
contracts.’’ Other parties use less
colorful language, but still indicate that
site commissions often ‘‘have nothing to
do with the provision’’ of ICS. We agree
with commenters opposed to recovery
of site commissions in ICS rates and
find that site commission payments
should not be included in our rate cap
calculations.
124. We therefore agree with inmate
advocates, such as the Wright
Petitioners and the Civil Rights
Coalition, a group of 20 national civil
rights and social justice organizations;
providers, such as CenturyLink and
NCIC; United States Senators; and state
regulators, such as the Alabama PSC
that, at this time, we should focus on
our core ratemaking authority in
reforming ICS and not prohibit or
specifically regulate site commission
payments. While we continue to view
such payments as an apportionment of
profit, and therefore irrelevant to the
costs we consider in setting rate caps for
ICS, we do not prohibit ICS providers
from paying site commissions. (Of
course, providers’ rates must comply
E:\FR\FM\18DER2.SGM
18DER2
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 80, No. 243 / Friday, December 18, 2015 / Rules and Regulations
with our rate caps, regardless of whether
the provider pays site commissions.)
125. The record supports excluding
site commission payments from the
costs used to calculate the rate caps for
ICS. Indeed, even many of the
commenters that oppose a prohibition
on site commissions urge the
Commission to consider only costs
related to the provision of ICS in
calculating the rate caps. If site
commissions were factored into the
costs we used to set the rate caps, the
caps would be significantly higher.
Passing the non-ICS-related costs that
comprise site commission payments
including contributions to general
revenue funds, onto inmates and their
families as part of the costs used to set
rate caps would result in rates that
exceed the fair compensation required
by section 276 and that are not just and
reasonable, as required by section 201.
126. We note that several commenters
argue that the programs currently
supported by site commissions should
be paid for out of tax funds collected
from the population at large, or from
other sources. HRDC, for example,
argues that ‘‘all taxpayers should fund
the cost of operating correctional
facilities, including the cost of
providing ICS,’’ just as homeowners pay
taxes to fund schools, regardless of
whether they have school-age children.
We need not reach such arguments to
support our decision. Rather, we
conclude that, because the programs in
question are unrelated to the provision
or use of ICS, the burden of paying for
them may not, under the
Communications Act, be imposed on
end users of ICS. As the Commission
has explained, how facilities use the site
commission payments they receive from
ICS providers is irrelevant to our
analysis: ‘‘[t]he Act does not provide a
mechanism for funding social welfare
programs or other costs unrelated to the
provision of ICS, no matter how
successful or worthy.’’ Consistent with
the record in this proceeding, as well as
the Commission’s decision in the 2013
Order, we therefore exclude site
commission payments from our rate cap
calculations.
127. In the Second FNPRM, the
Commission sought comment on
whether it could or should prohibit site
commissions. A variety of commenters
support such a prohibition, primarily
based on their belief that a rule against
site commissions is needed to ensure
that ICS rates are fair, just, and
reasonable. Other commenters,
primarily sheriffs and others associated
with correctional facilities, favor the
continued use of site commissions. As
noted above, many of these parties,
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:49 Dec 17, 2015
Jkt 238001
however, appear to be concerned mostly
with ensuring that facilities can recover
costs they incur in allowing access to
ICS. As a threshold matter, as noted
herein the record is not clear as to
whether the correctional facilities in fact
bear a cost in the provision of ICS that
is unique to the provision of phone
service in addition to the costs of
operating a correctional facility. The
record suggests that site commissions
are used mainly to fund a wide and
disparate range of activities, including
general governmental or correctional
activities unrelated to the costs of
providing ICS by either the provider or
facility. Even assuming facilities do
incur costs tied to the provision of ICS,
we have addressed such a concern by
not prohibiting providers from sharing
their profits with correctional facilities
to recover such costs, if appropriate.
Some of these commenters also argue
that site commissions should be
preserved because they provide an
important incentive for facilities to
make ICS available to their inmates.
Another group of commenters question
the Commission’s legal authority to
prohibit site commissions and argue
that prohibiting site commissions would
not produce any material benefit. A
number of commenters, representing a
wide range of interests, urge the
Commission to follow the lead of the
Alabama PSC and restrict site
commissions only indirectly, by
imposing caps on ICS providers’ rates,
thereby limiting the amount of profit
available to pay site commissions. The
Wright Petitioners, among others,
suggest that we adopt a similar
approach here, arguing that the
Commission should ‘‘simply establish
an ICS rate that complies with Sections
201, 205, and 276 of the Act, and let ICS
providers and correctional authorities
allocate the revenue in any manner they
wish.’’ ICS provider NCIC ‘‘agrees that
jails and prisons should be allowed [to
seek] site commission payments after
the FCC caps the rates, ancillary fees
and convenience payment options,
which will reduce commission
payments to reasonable levels to
provide cost-recovery.’’ GTL disagrees,
however, arguing that under the
Alabama model, ‘‘providers must
generate revenue to pay the
unconstrained site commissions . . .
which puts upward pressure on enduser prices.’’ In fact, GTL and others
contend that a regulatory regime that
permitted providers to make site
commission payments, but did not take
those payments into account in setting
the rates would result in an
unconstitutional ‘‘taking’’ in violation of
PO 00000
Frm 00019
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
79153
the Fifth Amendment, and is ‘‘arbitrary
and capricious.’’
128. Based on the evidence in the
record, we conclude that we do not
need to prohibit site commissions at this
time to achieve the statutory directives
of ensuring that ICS rates are just,
reasonable, and fair. The fact that we do
not prohibit site commission payments
does not mean, however, that we have
failed to address site commissions. To
the contrary, we have addressed the
harmful effects of outsized site
commissions by establishing
comprehensive rate caps and caps on
ancillary service charges that may limit
providers’ ability to pass site
commissions through to ICS consumers.
We have also made the considered
decision to establish caps on rates and
ancillary service charges and allow
market forces to dictate adjustments in
site commission payments. As noted
below, this approach is consistent with
the Commission’s general preference to
rely on market forces, rather than
regulatory intervention, wherever
reasonably possible. Our expectation
that ICS providers and correctional
facilities will find an approach that
meets their needs and complies with
our rate caps is neither arbitrary nor
capricious. In fact, evidence in the
record demonstrates that ICS rates can
be set at levels that are well within our
rate caps while allowing for fair
compensation and still leaving room for
site commission payments. For
example, in Pennsylvania, the perminute rate of $0.059 includes a 35
percent site commission. Similarly, in
New Hampshire, the state DOC lowered
intrastate rates to less than $0.06 per
minute with a 20 percent site
commission. Thus, it is possible to have
reasonable rates and fair compensation
without expressly prohibiting site
commissions.
129. We emphasize that the actions
we take here are based on our
ratemaking authority and are intended
to ensure fair, just, and reasonable ICS
rates. The caps and restrictions we
impose on providers’ rates should
eliminate or substantially reduce the
ability of site commissions to inflate
rates above providers’ costs or
reasonable profit to otherwise distort
ICS rates. As explained elsewhere in
this Order, we have seen some positive
steps toward the lowering and/or
elimination of site commissions and we
believe that this trend, coupled with the
actions we take today, constitutes a
reasonable means of addressing ICS
issues one step at a time, given the fact
that some portion of some site
commissions are said to represent the
recovery of reasonable institutional
E:\FR\FM\18DER2.SGM
18DER2
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES2
79154
Federal Register / Vol. 80, No. 243 / Friday, December 18, 2015 / Rules and Regulations
costs. We reiterate that we will,
however, continue to monitor the ICS
market and will not hesitate to take
additional action to prohibit site
commissions, if necessary.
130. Our decision not to prohibit site
commission payments should not be
viewed as an endorsement of such
practices. Rather, our decision simply
reflects our focus on achieving our
statutory objectives with only limited
regulatory intervention. We understand
the positions of those parties calling for
the regulation of site commission
practices, or even those calling for a
complete ban of them. We also
acknowledge that some commenters
have questioned our legal authority to
prohibit site commissions. Other parties
argue that we have clear authority to
regulate site commission payments.
Ultimately, however, we do not need to
determine whether we have authority to
ban site commission payments, given
our decision to take a less heavy-handed
approach, similar to that adopted by the
Alabama PSC. This approach is
consistent with the Commission’s
general preference to rely on market
forces, rather than regulatory fiat,
whenever possible.
131. We expect that the approach
adopted in this Order will result in
lower site commissions, and strongly
encourage additional jurisdictions to
eliminate site commissions altogether to
help ensure that inmates and their
families have access to ICS at affordable
rates. We applaud recent efforts by New
Jersey and Ohio to eliminate site
commissions. The per-minute intrastate
ICS rates in these states have dropped
considerably (from $0.15 to under $0.05
in New Jersey and $0.39 to $0.05 in
Ohio). Pay Tel estimates that in eight
states that have eliminated site
commissions the rates average less than
$0.07/minute. The actions taken by
these states demonstrate that site
commissions can be eliminated without
sacrificing facilities’ ability to
implement robust security protocols.
Additional states continue to take
similar steps to curb or prevent the use
of site commissions in their state prison
systems and we urge other states to take
similar actions. We also reiterate that
rates can be significantly below our rate
caps and still offer ICS providers
sufficient profit to allow them to pay
reasonable site commissions.
132. Further, we note that, despite
what some entities appear to suggest,
this Order does not maintain the status
quo in the ICS market. To the contrary,
we conclude that our actions in this
Order constitute changes in law and/or
instances of force majeure that are likely
to alter or trigger the renegotiation of
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:49 Dec 17, 2015
Jkt 238001
many ICS contracts. We also think it
reasonable to anticipate that ICS
providers are on notice of these changes
in law and, going forward, will not enter
into contracts promising exorbitant site
commission payments that they will not
be able to recover through their ICS
rates under our rate caps. Indeed, we
anticipate that the reforms adopted in
this Order will help recalibrate ICS
market competition by motivating
correctional facilities to evaluate bids
based on factors other than the highest
site commission. However, as noted
above, we will monitor the market and
will take appropriate action if our
prediction proves inaccurate.
a. Facility Costs Related To Providing
ICS
133. Background. In the Mandatory
Data Collection, the Commission
required ICS providers to submit their
costs related to the provision of ICS,
including their telecommunications,
equipment and security costs. For
example, in the Mandatory Data
Collection Instructions, the Bureau
directed ICS providers to include
‘‘security costs incurred by the ICS
provider in the provision of inmate
calling services, such as, but not limited
to, voice biometrics technology and call
recording and monitoring.’’ In their
responses, ICS providers indicated that
the data they filed included costs
associated with security features
relating to the provision of ICS.
134. In the Second FNPRM, the
Commission noted that the record todate was mixed regarding how much, if
anything, facilities spend on ICS. It
sought comment on the ‘‘actual costs’’
that facilities may incur in the provision
of ICS and the appropriate vehicle for
enabling facilities to recover such costs.
The Commission also sought comment
on whether any such costs should be
recoverable through the per-minute
rates ICS providers charge inmates and
their families. In response, some law
enforcement representatives assert that
correctional facilities incur costs related
to ‘‘call monitoring, responding to ICS
system alerts, responding to law
enforcement requests for records/
recordings, call recording analysis,
enrolling inmates for voice biometrics,
and other duties,’’ including
‘‘administrative duties’’ that arguably
are related to ICS. Some ICS providers,
however, contend that many of the
activities the facilities claim as ICSrelated costs are, in fact, handled by the
ICS provider. For example, Securus
states that it performs most ICS-related
tasks for facilities, including handling
U.S. Marshal inquiries, cell phone
detection and interception, listening to
PO 00000
Frm 00020
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
calls, and providing call recordings to
courts. Similarly, GTL explains that the
‘‘established industry protocol’’ is for
ICS providers to handle security duties
for the correctional facilities they serve,
either as part of a turnkey ICS product
or as a condition of the contract award,
regardless of the size of the facility.
135. Although some commenters
argue that allowing ICS creates costs for
facilities, others question whether
correctional facilities incur any costs
that should be passed on to consumers
as part of the per-minute rates for ICS.
One issue is whether the costs parties
seek to attribute to ICS are, in fact, costs
that facilities would incur regardless of
whether they allowed ICS. Andrew
Lipman, for example, argues that many
correctional facilities seek payment for
‘‘activities that have nothing to do with
the provision of a telecommunications
service.’’ These parties argue that the
costs facilities seek to pass on to ICS
providers and users are more properly
classified as law enforcement costs
related to operating a correctional
facility that should be borne by the
government and not ICS users.
136. Even commenters asserting that
facilities incur costs that are properly
attributable to the provision of ICS do
not agree on the extent of those costs.
A group of the largest ICS providers, for
example, notes that while they support
the recovery of ‘‘legitimate costs
incurred by correctional facilities that
are directly related to the provision of
inmate calling services,’’ they cannot
agree on how those costs should be
calculated. The NSA suggests that the
Commission approve a ‘‘compensation
amount for the security and
administrative duties performed in jails
in connection with ICS that is an
additive amount to the ICS rate.’’
Relying, in large part, on the results of
a survey it took of its members, as well
as analyses submitted by other parties,
NSA suggests that this additive amount
should range from $0.01 to $0.11 per
minute, depending on the size of the
facility being served.
137. Several commenters offer
critiques of NSA’s survey data, however.
GTL’s economic consultant, for
example, concludes that NSA’s latest
proposal would offer facilities
‘‘significantly larger’’ annual
compensation than would be justified
by estimates derived from the analyses
conducted by itself and other parties,
particularly for small facilities such as
jails with an ADP below 350. Even Pay
Tel, which generally supported the
NSA’s survey as a ‘‘robust and
significant dataset,’’ agrees that NSA
failed to remove outliers from its
calculations and that NSA included
E:\FR\FM\18DER2.SGM
18DER2
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 80, No. 243 / Friday, December 18, 2015 / Rules and Regulations
costs that are ‘‘typically associated with
on-going investigations that would not
be considered for Cost Recovery
purposes.’’ Andrew Lipman notes that
the NSA survey was based on only three
months of data from only approximately
five percent of NSA’s members and that
NSA had not provided any indication of
whether the survey respondents were
representative of NSA’s broader
membership. Mr. Lipman also points
out that the NSA did not provide the
raw data, a copy of the survey, any
information on the methodology used
by members to allocate time, or detailed
descriptions of the tasks encompassed
by various categories of costs, such as
‘‘administrative,’’ ‘‘security’’ or ‘‘other.’’
Relying on other evidence in the record,
Mr. Lipman suggests that it would be
unreasonable for providers to agree to
pay more than $0.01–$0.03 per minute
to reimburse facilities for any costs they
may incur in agreeing to make ICS
available to inmates. Darrell Baker of the
Alabama PSC recommends a cost
recovery rate of $0.04 per minute for
jails of all sizes and $0.01 to $0.02 per
minute for prisons, while an earlier
analysis from GTL yields median cost
recovery rates of $0.005 per minute for
prisons and $0.016 per minute for jails.
138. Discussion. The record contains
a wide range of conflicting views
regarding whether correctional facilities
incur any costs that are directly and
reasonably related to making ICS
available and that must be recovered
through ICS rates. As at least one
commenter points out, ICS continues to
be offered in states that have prohibited
payments from ICS providers to
facilities. This evidence undermines
claims that facilities incur unique costs
that are attributable to ICS and that must
be recovered from ICS rates. These
claims are further undermined by the
fact that ‘‘[n]one of the correctional
facilities and associations submitted
sufficient detail in this proceeding to
support the amount of their alleged
costs, or to demonstrate that these costs
meet the used and useful standard.’’
139. Some commenters argue that the
costs claimed by facilities are ‘‘basic law
enforcement activities [such as
surveillance and investigation of calls]
and not costs for providing a
telecommunications service.’’ The
record is not clear that the costs
facilities claim to incur due to ICS
would actually be eliminated if the
facilities ceased to allow inmates to
have access to ICS. Moreover, providers
indicate that costs that facilities claim to
incur in allowing ICS are, in fact, borne
directly by the providers. Those costs
are already built into our rate cap
calculations and should not be
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:49 Dec 17, 2015
Jkt 238001
recovered through an ‘‘additive’’ to the
ICS rates. Accordingly, while we
strongly encourage the elimination of
site commission payments, we do not
dictate what an ICS provider can do
with its profits and conclude that the
most reasonable and fair approach is to
leave it to ICS providers and facilities to
negotiate the amount of any payments
from the providers to the facilities,
provided that those payments do not
drive the provider’s rates above the
applicable rate cap. We note, however,
that evidence submitted in the record—
and discussed above—indicates that if
facilities incurred any legitimate costs
in connection with ICS, those costs
would likely amount to no more than
one or two cents per billable minute.
Our rate caps are sufficiently generous
to cover any such costs.
140. As noted above, some parties
contend that correctional facilities will
remove or limit access to telephones if
the Commission acts to limit site
commission payments. We find it highly
unlikely, however, that facilities would
eliminate or limit access to ICS as a
result of this Order. Given that we do
not ban site commissions, facilities have
no basis for taking such extreme
measures. Notably, the record contains
no indication that ICS deployment has
decreased in states that have eliminated
site commissions. This is unsurprising,
given what we anticipate would be an
intensely negative backlash to such an
action. In addition, the record indicates
that ICS provides valuable, nonmonetary benefits to correctional
facilities, such as correctional
management and incentives to inmates
who exhibit good behavior.
b. Ensuring Fair Compensation
141. Some parties argue that it would
be confiscatory for the Commission to
exclude the costs of site commission
payments from our rate cap calculations
without also explicitly prohibiting ICS
providers from paying such
commissions. According to these
parties, ICS providers will not be able to
afford the site commission payments
demanded of them by correctional
facilities if the providers’ revenues are
limited by the rate caps established
here. These claims rest largely on the
fact that existing ICS contracts may
obligate providers to pay site
commissions to the facilities they are
serving. As explained further below, we
conclude that these concerns are largely
unfounded.
142. For the same reasons set forth in
the 2013 Order, we reject arguments that
the reforms we adopt herein effectuate
unconstitutional takings. The offering of
ICS is voluntary on the part of ICS
PO 00000
Frm 00021
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
79155
providers, who are in the best position
to decide whether to bid to offer service
subject to the contours of the request for
proposal (RFP). There is no obligation
on the part of the ICS provider to submit
bids or to do so at rates that would be
insufficient to meet the costs of serving
the facility or result in unfair
compensation. We also reiterate that our
rate caps are based on the reported costs
that the providers themselves submitted
into the record without any adjustment
by the Commission. Thus, the rate caps
provide ample room for an
economically efficient provider of ICS to
earn a reasonable profit on its services.
The fact that our rate caps do not
include an explicit allowance for site
commission payments does not render
them confiscatory. As explained above,
the record does not support a
conclusion that site commission
payments are costs that are ‘‘reasonably
related to the provision of ICS.’’ The fact
that providers choose to pay site
commissions is not enough to render
them compensable through the ICS rate,
particularly in light of section 276’s
requirement that ICS compensation
must be ‘‘fair.’’ Excluding site
commission payments from the rate cap
calculation is no different than
excluding any other cost that is not
reasonably related to the provision of
the service. For example, if a provider
decided to purchase a fleet of private
jets to ferry its executives from place to
place, we would not prohibit such an
expenditure, but—because the purchase
of private jets is not ‘‘reasonably
related’’ to the provision of ICS—we
would not include such an expense in
the costs used to determine a fair
compensation rate for ICS.
143. In addition, we re-emphasize that
a party carries a heavy burden if it seeks
to demonstrate that a regulation creates
an unconstitutional ‘‘taking.’’ For
instance, to succeed on a ‘‘takings’’
claim, a party must demonstrate that the
losses caused by the regulation in
question are so significant that the ‘‘net
effect’’ is confiscatory. When confronted
with a ‘‘takings’’ claim, courts will
examine the net effect of the regulation
on the company’s enterprise as a whole,
rather than on a specific product or
service. Thus, it is not enough for a
provider to show that it is losing money
on a particular service or in serving a
particular customer. Instead, a provider
seeking to show that our rate caps are
confiscatory will have to demonstrate
that any cognizable harm caused by our
regulations is so severe that it meets the
high bar for a takings with respect to the
company as a whole, e.g., by
‘‘destroying the value of [the provider’s]
E:\FR\FM\18DER2.SGM
18DER2
79156
Federal Register / Vol. 80, No. 243 / Friday, December 18, 2015 / Rules and Regulations
property for all the purposes for which
it was acquired.’’ Moreover, providers
have been on notice for years that the
Commission might adopt rate caps, or
even eliminate site commissions. Thus,
any claims that our actions today upset
‘‘investment-backed expectations of ICS
providers’’ are likely to fail, particularly
claims from providers that recently
entered into new contracts with high
site commissions in an effort to
circumvent possible Commission
regulations. We find it unlikely that our
rates will result in a ‘‘taking,’’ but the
waiver process described below should
offer providers an adequate avenue for
relief if they find our ICS regulations
unworkable.
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES2
C. Ancillary Service Charges and Taxes
1. Background
144. The record contains evidence
that ancillary service charges have
increased since the 2013 Order, which
highlights the fact that, absent reform,
ICS providers have the ability and
incentive to continue to increase such
charges unchecked by competitive
forces. Indeed, the continuing growth in
the number and dollar amount of
ancillary service charges represents
another example of market failure
necessitating Commission action. These
charges are unchecked by market forces
because inmates and their families must
either incur them when making a call or
forego contact with their loved ones.
Ancillary service charges inflate the
effective price consumers pay for ICS.
According to some estimates, ancillary
service charges may represent as much
as 38 percent of total consumer ICS
payments. The sheer number of
ancillary service charges, their varying
nomenclature, and the variability of the
amounts charged make for a confusing
system.
145. The record overwhelmingly
supports the need to reform ancillary
service charges. While we would prefer
to allow the market to discipline rates,
the evidence since the Commission’s
2013 Order confirms that ancillary
service charges have not only increased,
but new charges have appeared. We find
our statutory directive requires us to
adopt reforms to limit ancillary service
charges. As described below, we adopt
caps for certain ancillary fees, and we
prohibit all other charges that are
ancillary to ICS.
146. Our Mandatory Data Collection
confirmed that various ICS providers
charge a plethora of ancillary service
charges, and that different providers
may describe the same charge by
different names. Commenters suggest
that ancillary service charges inflate the
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:49 Dec 17, 2015
Jkt 238001
cost of ICS to end users without
justification. For example, some
providers charge account set-up,
maintenance, closure, and refund fees.
Praeses contends that ‘‘[p]roviders
should not be permitted to charge any
ancillary fees to recover . . . intrinsic
ICS costs, such as validation fees or fees
related to Facility-required security.’’
This distinction between what is an
intrinsic part of providing ICS, and what
is not, has helped us to select the
ancillary service charges we find
appropriate and to ban all other
ancillary service charges.
147. In responding to the unique
challenges posed by escalating ancillary
fees, this Order establishes a limited list
of ancillary fees that the Commission
will permit ICS providers to charge. The
amount of each of these fees is capped,
and ICS providers are restricted from
charging any ancillary fees not
specifically allowed in our Order. For
fees for single-call and related services
and third-party financial transaction
fees, we allow providers to pass through
only the charges they incur without any
additional markup. We limit automated
payment fees to $3.00, live agent fees to
$5.95, and paper statement fees to $2.00.
Apart from these specific fees, no
additional ancillary service charges are
allowed. Taxes are discussed separately
and must be passed through with no
markup. We also take action to avoid
potential loopholes in these rules, such
as artificial limits on minimum and
maximum account balances that could
require inmates to reload accounts
frequently and unnecessarily increase
costs borne by consumers. This
approach involved analyzing the data
submitted by carriers, as well as
comments in the record, to determine
which fees ICS providers should
legitimately be able to charge end users.
2. Discussion
148. Review of Ancillary Service
Charges in the Record. In response to
the Mandatory Data Collection, the
Commission received some data
regarding ancillary service charges, but
providers did not follow consistent
approaches in assessing and labeling
such fees, and allocated and reported
these costs in inconsistent ways.
Accordingly, in the Second FNPRM the
Commission sought comment on these
data inconsistencies and on the
ancillary service charge data generally.
The Commission also sought comment
on prohibiting separate ancillary service
charges for functions that are typically
part of normal utility overhead and
should be included in the rate for any
basic ICS offering, and asked if certain
types of ancillary service charges, such
PO 00000
Frm 00022
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
as refund charges, should be disallowed
altogether.
149. In response to the Second
FNPRM, commenters disagreed over the
exact nature of the reforms that should
be implemented, but the majority agreed
that many or all ancillary service
charges should be eliminated. ICS
provider CTEL claims that ancillary
service charges, not site commissions,
drive high ICS calling rates. ICS users
also supported reforming ancillary
service charges with examples of the
impact of such charges on their ability
to make calls. Even when consumers are
made aware of the fees, they can still
seem unjustified or unclear. The record
indicates that ICS providers can receive
fair compensation and provide secure
services with a simplified ancillary
service charge structure.
150. Prohibiting Ancillary Service
Charges. The Commission sought
comment on prohibiting ancillary
service charges altogether. Certain
parties argued that the best approach to
ancillary service charges was to ban
them outright. The Wright Petitioners,
for example, contend that no cost data
in the record justifies the existence of
ancillary fees, and that ancillary fees
differ significantly among providers for
no reason except that ICS providers will
charge as much as they can. If the
Commission does not eliminate
ancillary service charges, then the
Wright Petitioners contend that any
rules addressing ancillary service
charges must specifically identify the
fees that may be charged and prohibit
all others. PLS argues the Commission
should prohibit ancillary service
charges because many of these fees bear
no relation to ICS costs.
151. Reducing Categories of Ancillary
Service Charges. The Commission also
sought comment on limiting the number
of allowable ancillary service charges.
Many commenters support this
approach as enabling ICS providers to
still earn a profit, while providing their
services at just and reasonable rates.
CenturyLink explains that ‘‘the overall
cost of ICS to inmate families will not
be reduced without restrictions on
ancillary fees’’ and recommends that the
Commission ‘‘eliminate all but a narrow
class of ancillary fees and impose
reasonable rate caps on those that it
allows.’’ One commenter explains that
ancillary fees have ‘‘no actual relation to
actual costs borne by ICS providers and
have become a mechanism by which
providers sustain or increase their
overall revenues.’’ Indeed, even ICS
providers have recognized the need for
reform and have submitted various
proposals to that end.
E:\FR\FM\18DER2.SGM
18DER2
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 80, No. 243 / Friday, December 18, 2015 / Rules and Regulations
152. Parties differ about which
ancillary service charges should be
capped. For example, a number of
commenters believe that the
Commission should eliminate all fees
for services that a consumer is required
to pay in order to access basic ICS,
including, but not limited to, account
set-up, maintenance, funding, refund,
and closure fees. In addition, Praeses
suggests that ‘‘[a]ll costs that Providers
necessarily and unavoidably incur as
part of completing an inmate call should
be recovered through ICS rates. As a
result, Providers should not be
permitted to charge any ancillary fees to
recover such intrinsic ICS costs, such as
validation fees or fees related to
Facility-required security.’’
153. Of additional concern is the
ability of ICS providers to evade any
limitation on a particular ancillary
service charge simply by changing its
name. ICSolutions notes that if an RFP
for ICS prohibits a specific fee, some
bidding ICS providers simply rename it
or create a new fee to take its place.
Other commenters contend that if ICS
providers want to impose additional
ancillary service charges, then they
should ask for a waiver from the
Commission or a rule modification.
154. This concerns us because it
suggests that ICS providers are using
ancillary service charges as a loophole
to increase revenues and undermine the
impact of the interstate rate caps
adopted in the 2013 Order. Illustrating
the impact this trend has on consumers,
Pay Tel explains that if a family has
$100 to spend on inmate calling for the
month, ancillary fees can consume up to
$60, leaving only $40 for the actual
phone calls. Ancillary fees often
increase the average cost of a 15-minute
call to as much as $8.33, more than
double the price of a 15-minute call at
the Commission’s interim rate caps
adopted in the 2013 Order. Some
commenters also raise concerns that
some ICS providers may impose unfair
rates by instituting minimum or
maximum amounts that may be
deposited for prepaid calling accounts.
155. Proposals in the Record. The
Commission has focused on market
failure with regard to unchecked and
escalating ancillary service charges in
this proceeding, including releasing a
public notice prior to the 2013 Order
seeking additional information about
this topic. Since 2012, the Commission
has received several proposals detailing
comprehensive ICS reform approaches,
and had the benefit of observing real
world models regulating ancillary
service charges.
156. Alabama PSC Reforms. In the
Second FNPRM, the Commission noted
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:49 Dec 17, 2015
Jkt 238001
that the Alabama PSC had implemented
an approach to ancillary service charges
that both limited the kinds of allowable
ancillary service charges and capped the
fees for those charges. Specifically, the
Alabama PSC authorized, but capped,
separate ancillary service charges for
particular services, including a $3.00
maximum fee for debit/credit card
payment, $5.95 maximum fee for
payment via live agent, $3.00 maximum
cap for bill processing for collect calls
billed by a call recipient’s local
telecommunications service provider,
$5.95 maximum cap on third-party
payment services, five percent cap on
inmate canteen/trust fund transfers, and
a $2.00 maximum cap on paper billing
statements. The Commission sought
comment on this approach.
157. In the Second FNPRM, the
Commission specifically asked whether
the Alabama PSC’s rate caps for credit
card payments ($3.00 maximum) and
live operator assisted payments ($5.95)
would be appropriate for the
Commission to adopt. Many
commenters seeking to reform ancillary
service charges focused not only on
reducing the kinds of ancillary service
charges that may be imposed, but also
on imposing caps on the fees that may
be charged for the approved ancillary
service charges. Some commenters
expressed concern that unreasonable
costs would continue to be passed
through to end users if regulations only
specified the ancillary service charges
that may be levied, without also
imposing caps on those charges.
158. Joint Provider Proposal. In the
Second FNPRM, the Commission also
sought comment on the Joint Provider
Proposal’s suggestions for ancillary
service charge reform. This proposal
would voluntarily eliminate a number
of types of fees, including per-call fees,
account set-up fees, billing statement
fees, account close-out and refund fees,
wireless administration fees, voice
biometrics and other technology fees,
and regulatory assessment fees, and cap
charges for non-eliminated fees. The
Joint Provider Proposal supported a
$7.95 cap for three years on debit/credit
card payment or deposit fees, a cap for
three years at existing fees (as high as
$14.99) for calls billed to a credit card
and as high as $9.99 for calls billed to
a mobile phone, and a cap on money
transfer fees at the existing level (as high
as $11.95), plus a $2.50 administrative
fee cap. Joint Provider Proposal
supporters claim that their proposal will
‘‘dramatically alter the economic
landscape of the ICS industry, making it
possible for providers to forego many
fees and cap others at current levels.’’
PO 00000
Frm 00023
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
79157
159. Some commenters criticize the
Joint Provider Proposal as retaining the
most lucrative ancillary service charges,
and undermining reform efforts by
allowing the large providers to maintain
their dominant positions. CTEL asserts
that smaller ICS providers lack the
market power to impose high ancillary
service charges. The Alabama PSC also
states that it ‘‘cannot emphasize strongly
enough that the outliers in terms of
excessive ancillary fees are the
providers that submitted the Proposal to
the Commission.’’
160. Pay Tel Proposal. On October 3,
2014, Pay Tel submitted an ex parte
describing a proposal for comprehensive
reform, including rate reform, a
proposed approach for site commission
payments, reporting requirements, and a
proposal for ancillary service charge
reform. The Commission sought
comment on this proposal in the Second
FNPRM. The Wright Petitioners agree
with Pay Tel that there should be
specific guidelines for the disclosure of
rate and ancillary fee information.’’ The
Alabama PSC, Wright Petitioners,
CenturyLink, and NCIC agree with Pay
Tel’s suggested ancillary service charge
rate caps in a number of respects.
Securus, however, argues that Pay Tel
mischaracterizes the Joint Provider
Proposal, and that, to justify its own
proposal, Pay Tel grossly overestimates
the amount of ancillary service charges
that consumers will have to pay under
the Joint Provider Proposal.
3. Establishing Limited List of Permitted
Ancillary Service Charges
161. After careful consideration of the
record, including analysis of the
Mandatory Data Collection, we
conclude that reform is necessary to
address ever-increasing fees that are
unchecked by competitive forces and
unrelated to costs. ICS providers, which
typically have exclusive contracts to
serve a facility, have the incentive and
ability to continue to extract unjust and
unreasonable ancillary service charges.
As a result, we conclude it is necessary
to reform the ancillary service charge
structure imposed on consumers by ICS
providers, as shown in Table Four
below. All other ancillary service
charges not specifically included in
Table Four are prohibited. (Thus,
providers would be prohibited from
imposing charges for biometric
technology, for example.) We conclude
that the allowable charges will facilitate
communications between inmates and
their loved ones and will allow ICS
providers to recover the costs incurred
for providing the ancillary service
associated with the relevant fee. We find
no other examples in the record of
E:\FR\FM\18DER2.SGM
18DER2
79158
Federal Register / Vol. 80, No. 243 / Friday, December 18, 2015 / Rules and Regulations
ancillary services that are actually
provided today and that have a cost that
warrants recovery.
162. Our approach is supported by the
record and will reduce the cost of
service for millions of consumers. Even
so, as with all reforms adopted in this
Order, we will reevaluate these charges
in two years to determine if adjustments
are appropriate. We expect that these
caps will serve as backstops as
efficiencies are gained by providers, and
contracts are changed, or new contracts
are entered into between parties. For
example, the record indicates that the
recently-adopted New Jersey state
correctional institutions’ ICS contract
specifically prohibits ‘‘discretionary
fees,’’ which include bill statement fees,
monthly recurring wireless account
maintenance charges, account setup
fees, funding fees, refund fees, and a
single bill fee. Finally, we believe it is
reasonable to expect that the ancillary
service charge caps may encourage
providers to more efficiently provide
ancillary services, potentially
stimulating competition among ICS
providers to the added benefit of
consumers and in keeping with section
276’s statutory mandate. The reforms
are intended to facilitate the proper
functioning of the ICS market.
163. Each of the entries in Table Four
focuses on the particular functions
related to each type of charge listed
below. (Thus, even if a provider
renames one of its fees to match the
terminology in this table, that will not
be sufficient to make an allowable
ancillary service charge. Also, each
individual ancillary service charge that
an ICS provider levies must serve one of
the permitted functions in order to
qualify as a permissible ancillary service
charge, regardless of the precise
terminology used. In the event of
dispute, the Commission will evaluate
the fee charged to a consumer on the
basis of the totality of the
circumstances, judged from a reasonable
consumer’s point of view, to determine
whether the fee serves one of the
permitted functions. Automated
payments include payments by
interactive voice response (IVR), web,
and kiosk.)
TABLE FOUR
Permitted ancillary service charges and taxes
Monetary cap per use/instruction
Applicable taxes and regulatory fees .......................................................
Provider shall pass these charges through to consumers directly with
no markup.
$3.00.
Provider shall directly pass through third-party financial transaction fees
with no markup, plus adopted, per-minute rate.
$5.95.
Automated payment fees .........................................................................
Fees for single-call and related services, e.g., direct bill to mobile
phone without setting up an account.
Live agent fee, i.e., phone payment or account set up with optional use
of a live operator.
Paper bill/statement fees (no charge permitted for electronic bills/statements).
Prepaid account funding minimums and maximums ...............................
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES2
Third-party financial transaction fees, e.g., MoneyGram, Western
Union, credit card processing fees and transfers from third-party
commissary accounts.
164. Data Analysis. Based on our
analysis of the ancillary service charge
cost data submitted in response to the
Mandatory Data Collection and the
record, we conclude that the caps we
adopt for ancillary service charges will
allow ICS providers to recover their
reported costs attributable to providing
these services and earn fair
compensation. Ten of the fourteen ICS
providers that submitted data in
response to the Mandatory Data
Collection included cost and revenue
data for ancillary service charges. One
provider did not report any direct costs
related to ancillary service charges and
one provider reported only one ancillary
service charge. The reported rates for
ancillary service charges range from
$0.08 to $10.97 per use for automated
payments, from $2.49 to $5.95 per use
for transactions handled by a live agent,
and from $1.50 to $5.00 for paper billing
fees. In comparison, ICS providers
report that they incur costs for ancillary
service charges ranging from $0.10 to
$6.58 when they offer automated
payments, $2.49 to $5.26 when they
offer transactions handled by a live
agent, and $0.08 to $2.88 when they
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:49 Dec 17, 2015
Jkt 238001
$2.00.
Prohibit prepaid account funding minimums and prohibit prepaid account funding maximums under $50.
Provider shall pass this charge through to end user directly, with no
markup.
offer paper billing. These numbers serve
to illustrate the enormous difference
between the charges imposed on ICS
end users and the much lower costs to
ICS providers of offering those services.
The ancillary service charge caps we
have selected fall within a reasonable
range of the reported costs for the
services, and are supported by the
record for each fee cap as explained
below.
165. We also note that some
jurisdictions have banned ancillary
service charges and that providers have
complied with such regulations. This
suggests that ancillary service costs can
be recovered with reasonable ICS rates.
Accordingly, our ancillary service
charge caps should more than
adequately compensate for the costs
incurred. Moreover, we conclude that
the annual reporting, certification and
data collection requirements adopted
herein regarding ancillary fee
information will ensure compliance
with the requirements. We will use this
information to ensure that ICS providers
are complying with the reforms adopted
herein.
PO 00000
Frm 00024
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
166. Ancillary Services Charge Cap
Methodology. The reforms we adopt
herein represent a middle ground
between the various proposals in the
record. First, we determined which
categories of ancillary service charges
should be allowed. Next, we evaluated
the information obtained through our
Mandatory Data Collection as discussed
above, and comments in the record
addressing the specific proposals in and
in response to the Second FNPRM. We
conclude that prohibiting ICS providers
from recovering their costs reasonably
and directly related to making available
an ancillary service would not allow ICS
providers to receive fair compensation
for those services. We also conclude that
certain proposed high ancillary service
charges, such as those in the Joint
Provider Proposal, would result in
excessively compensatory fees and
would violate our requirement to make
ICS rates just, reasonable and fair to end
users. Therefore, we adopt caps on fees
for ancillary service charges that will
allow ICS providers to recover the costs
incurred for providing the ancillary
service associated with the relevant fee
while ensuring just, reasonable, and fair
E:\FR\FM\18DER2.SGM
18DER2
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 80, No. 243 / Friday, December 18, 2015 / Rules and Regulations
rates to end users. Below we explain the
analysis that went into determining the
appropriate cap for each category of
permitted ancillary service charge.
167. Automated Payment Fee. We
permit up to a $3.00 automated payment
fee for credit card, debit card, and bill
processing fees, including payments
made by interactive voice response
(IVR), web, or kiosk. This approach is
supported by the record and more than
ensures that ICS providers can recoup
the costs of offering these services. The
Commission specifically sought
comment on automated payment fees in
the Second FNPRM. For example, the
Commission asked whether a $3.00 cap
for debit and credit card payment fees
via the web, an IVR, or a kiosk was an
appropriate charge. We find support for
our approach from numerous
commenters, including the Alabama
PSC, which concluded, as we do, that a
$3.00 cap for credit card processing and
bill processing is appropriate. This
$3.00 cap is also supported by Pay Tel,
which charges this amount for
automated payments. In addition,
multiple parties support this approach
in the record, including the Wright
Petitioners, CenturyLink, and NCIC—all
of which agree this amount is an
appropriate cap for automated
payments. Securus, one of the largest
ICS providers in the market, asserted
that allowing end users to pay with
credit cards costs the company more
than $3.00. The credit-card processing
costs that Securus cites indicate to us
that it is an outlier, especially since, as
just discussed, companies that are much
smaller than Securus acknowledge that
they can process credit card payments at
a $3.00 rate. We find that a $3.00 cap
on automated payments is supported by
the reported costs of providing the
service as opposed to other rates for the
service.
168. Live Agent Payment Fee or
Account Set Up. We allow ICS
providers to recover up to $5.95 when
consumers choose to make use of an
optional live operator to complete ICS
transactions. We have recognized that
interaction with a live operator to
complete ICS transactions may add to
the costs of providing ICS. Thus, we
allow an ancillary service charge to
compensate providers for offering this
optional service. As with the other
ancillary service charges we have
determined are appropriate, in the
Second FNPRM, the Commission also
specifically asked commenters about the
$5.95 maximum fee for live operator
assisted payments. For the live agent
phone payment of $5.95 that we adopt,
we note that multiple ICS providers
including, CenturyLink, NCIC, and Pay
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:49 Dec 17, 2015
Jkt 238001
Tel, as well as the Wright Petitioners,
and the Alabama PSC, all agree that this
is the correct rate. This $5.95 fee may
only be charged once per interaction
with a live operator, regardless of the
number of tasks completed in the call,
and live operator calls may not be
terminated in order to attempt to charge
this fee an additional time. We will
monitor any complaints we receive with
regard to the live agent fee that suggest
that providers are attempting to
circumvent the limitations this rule sets
forth.
169. Paper Bill/Statement Fee. We
permit a cap of $2.00 for optional paper
billing statements. In the Second
FNPRM, the Commission noted that the
Alabama PSC had capped the charge for
a paper bill or statement, and asked
commenters to explain whether this,
and other approaches taken by the
Alabama PSC, were reasonable and
would lead to just and reasonable rates
and fair ICS compensation. Multiple
commenters agreed. Specifically, the
$2.00 paper bill charge we adopt is
supported by the Wright Petitioners, Pay
Tel, and the Alabama PSC, while
CenturyLink argues that the rate should
be marginally higher at $2.50 per bill.
170. Third-Party Financial
Transaction Fee. In the Second FNPRM,
the Commission asked how it should
ensure that money transfer service fees
paid by ICS consumers are just and
reasonable and fair. The record
establishes that inmates’ families
frequently do not have bank accounts,
and therefore rely on third-party money
transfer services such as Western Union
or MoneyGram to fund calls with
inmates. Third-party financial
transaction fees as discussed herein
consist of two elements. The first
element is the transfer of funds from a
consumer via the third-party service,
i.e., Western Union or MoneyGram, to
an inmate’s ICS account. (We use these
two services as an example but do not
foreclose the possibility that there are
other third-party financial transaction
services. Credit card payment
processing also falls under the
discussion here.) The second element is
the ICS provider’s additional charge
imposed on end users for processing the
funds transferred via the third party
provider for the purpose of paying for
ICS calls. We find that this first aspect
of third-party financial transaction, e.g.,
the money transfers or credit card
payments, does not constitute ‘‘ancillary
services’’ within the meaning of section
276. The record suggests that ICS
providers have limited control over the
fees established by third parties, such as
Western Union or credit card
PO 00000
Frm 00025
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
79159
companies, for payment processing
functions.
171. However, the record indicates
that ICS providers are imposing
significant additional charges, as high as
$11.95, for end users to make account
payments via third parties, such as
Western Union or Money Gram, and
sharing the resulting profit with those
third-party financial institutions. We
find that the ICS providers’ additional
fee or mark-up to the third-parties’
service charges function as a billingand-collection related charge, on top of
the third-party charge, that the
Commission has authority to address.
Providers have offered no cost-based
justification for imposing an additional
fee on end users on top of the thirdparty money-transfer service or financial
institution fee, nor have they explained
what (if any) functions they must
necessarily perform to ‘‘process’’ a
transfer already transferred from the
third-party provider. Therefore, as
discussed in more detail below, we
require that ICS providers pass through
to their end users, with no additional
markup, the money transfer or thirdparty financial transaction fees they are
charged by such third parties. (The
record indicates that no additional
markup is warranted on top of the fees
charged by the third-party payment
providers.)
172. Our adopted approach ensures
that, in transactions like these, ICS
providers do not receive excessive
compensation, while also protecting
consumers from unreasonable
additional fees that result in unjust and
unreasonable ICS rates. We find support
for our third-party financial transaction
fee approach from parties such as
CenturyLink and NCIC, and the
Alabama PSC additionally urges the
Commission to require ICS providers to
‘‘eliminate the provider ancillary charge
premium they assess on top of the $5.95
payment transfer fee available to their
customers from Western Union and
MoneyGram.’’
173. Prohibited Fees. As explained
above, our approach to fees charged for
ancillary services specifically
enumerates the charges permitted and
bans all other ancillary service charges.
We find no other examples in the record
of ancillary services that are actually
provided today and that have a cost that
warrants recovery. While we place
limits on the types of ancillary service
charges we allow, we note that it is
important to have payment options that
permit the consumer simply to pay for
service without incurring any additional
charges. Many commenters, including
ICS providers, agree that these basic or
standard methods, such as making
E:\FR\FM\18DER2.SGM
18DER2
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES2
79160
Federal Register / Vol. 80, No. 243 / Friday, December 18, 2015 / Rules and Regulations
payments by check or money order,
must remain available without charge.
Securus, for example, has assured the
Commission that ‘‘[p]ayment by check
or money order always will be available
and free of charge.’’ In accordance with
our decision to allow only the specific
ancillary service charges we enumerate
in this Order, we clarify that no charges
are permissible for payment by check or
money order.
174. At this time, we do not find it
necessary to eliminate all ancillary
service charges to be consistent with our
statutory objectives and policy goals for
ICS reform. We are mindful of and
concerned about the potential for
continued abuse of ancillary service
charges, and we will monitor the
implementation of these caps and
determine if additional reforms are
necessary in the future. By limiting the
scope of ancillary service charges, we
also resolve other problems presented in
the record. We prohibit all other
ancillary service charges not
enumerated because the record did not
demonstrate that any other ancillary
services are reasonably and directly
related to the provision of ICS, nor are
they necessary to ensure that ICS
providers receive fair compensation for
providing service. Permitting any other
ancillary service charges would promote
unfair, unjust, and unreasonable rates to
end users, and would thus be contrary
to our statutory mandate. Further, we
find that removing a substantial number
of unjustifiable charges not only benefits
consumers, but also reduces compliance
costs for ICS providers by allowing them
easily to identify whether a particular
charge is permitted by our rules.
Additionally, since we have determined
that the only justifiable ancillary service
charges are the ones we specifically
enumerated, there are no countervailing
costs that would outweigh our selected
approach.
175. Purchase Minimums and
Maximums. In the Second FNPRM, the
Commission asked commenters whether
anything should be done about policies,
such as funding minimums and
maximums that may restrict consumers’
access to ICS. In response, some parties
raise concerns that some ICS providers
are engaging in unjust and unreasonable
practices and imposing unfair rates by
instituting minimum or maximum
amounts that may be deposited for
prepaid calling accounts. CenturyLink,
for example, contends that ‘‘[p]roviders
might impose high purchase minimums
and complex refund policies to obtain
captured funds. Providers might also
adopt low purchase maximums to force
customers to have to repeatedly repurchase services and generate
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:49 Dec 17, 2015
Jkt 238001
transaction fees.’’ Similarly, ICSolutions
urges the Commission to regulate
minimum and maximum funding
requirements, arguing that high
minimum funding requirements ‘‘can
preclude consumers from receiving calls
from their loved ones,’’ while low
maximums can force consumers to
‘‘fund their account more frequently, so
that [the provider] can charge more
ancillary fee payments.’’ Furthermore,
NCIC points out that ‘‘payments for
prepaid service by money order or
check [are] available free of charge to
ICS end users but this payment method
is frequently impractical because of the
excessive latency involved in
establishing service (up to ten days for
some providers).’’ Thus, inmates are
essentially forced into entering into
more costly prepaid options, many of
which require minimum payments and/
or impose maximum limits on deposits.
176. We agree that high purchase
minimum requirements can lead to
unfair compensation by forcing
consumers to deposit relatively large
sums of money even if they only want
to make one short call or by driving
consumers to more expensive calling
options. Thus, high purchase minimums
can effectively allow providers to charge
exorbitant amounts for single calls.
Such a result would be antithetical to
the Commission’s goals and to the
requirements of sections 201 and 276.
177. An artificial limit on maximum
account deposits could also lead to
gaming and loopholes. CenturyLink
points out that low maximums on
deposits can allow providers to increase
transaction fees. A provider may refuse
to permit a consumer from depositing
more than a certain amount of money
into an inmate calling account in a
single transaction, thereby compelling
the consumer to engage in additional
transactions and, as a result, incur
multiple ancillary service charges. Thus,
providers could circumvent our reforms
by placing artificially low limits on
deposits and requiring consumers to
incur ancillary charges every time they
add additional money to an account.
178. In order to prevent ICS providers
from obtaining unfair compensation by
inflating costs for end users relating to
maximum and minimum deposits, we
prohibit ICS providers from instituting
prepaid account minimums, and require
that any provider that limits deposits to
set the maximum purchase amount at
no less than $50 per transaction. Data
from the Mandatory Data Collection
show that the average call length
reported by respondents was
approximately 13 minutes. Under our
new rate structure, that means the
average cost of a call from a prison
PO 00000
Frm 00026
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
would be about $1.43. Accordingly, a
$50 maximum per transaction would
mean that consumers will be able to
make a relatively large number of calls
with a single deposit (on average about
35 calls). We find that allowing a lower
limit would create an unacceptable risk
that providers would be able to compel
consumers to incur multiple ancillary
service charges, as explained above. We
note, however, that the record also
reflects concerns that setting the floor
for maximum allowable deposits too
low could create risks for ICS providers,
including the potential for fraud.
Allowing providers to institute
maximum deposit amounts, but
requiring that those maximums be no
lower than $50, strikes a reasonable
balance between the competing
concerns expressed in the record. We
also note that various providers have
instituted maximum deposit policies
that conform to our requirement of no
less than a $50 maximum per
transaction, and in some circumstances
have even instituted higher maximum
deposit limits. As noted below, we will
continue to monitor the ICS marketplace
and to investigate any attempts, such as
these, to circumvent our rate caps or our
rules governing ancillary charges. Due
to the history of the large number and
ever-changing and growing nature of
ancillary service charges, as described
in the record, we will be diligent in
identifying any providers that violate
the new rules covering ancillary service
charges, third-party financial
transaction fees, and minimum and
maximum account funding.
Accordingly, we delegate to the Bureau
the authority to clarify the rule as
necessary, after public notice and an
opportunity to comment, where
appropriate, to ensure that the reforms
adopted in this Order relating to
ancillary service charges and third-party
financial transaction fees are properly
reflected. This includes seeking
comment on prohibiting additional
ancillary fees if there is evidence of
abuse of the permitted charges.
4. Cost-Benefit Analysis
179. After careful consideration, we
find that our approach to adopt simple
ancillary service charge caps provides
significant and important benefits to ICS
end users, outweighing any potential
burdens to providers. As discussed
above, we conclude that reform is
necessary to address ever-increasing and
multiplying fees that are unchecked by
competitive forces and unrelated to
costs. We find that the allowable
ancillary service charges will facilitate
communications between inmates and
their families, while enabling ICS
E:\FR\FM\18DER2.SGM
18DER2
Federal Register / Vol. 80, No. 243 / Friday, December 18, 2015 / Rules and Regulations
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES2
providers to recover the costs incurred
for providing the associated ancillary
services.
180. It is clear that market failure
exists with regard to ancillary service
charges. Numerous parties cite specific
instances of such market failure or
abuse among ancillary service charge
categories. Additionally, commenters
request the Commission take action to
curb these abuses by adopting reforms.
181. By creating simple rate caps and
limiting the scope of ancillary service
charges, we resolve these problems and
reform ancillary charges. We prohibit all
ancillary service charges not specifically
allowed, not only for the foregoing
reasons, but also because the record did
not demonstrate that any other ancillary
services are reasonably and directly
related to the provision of ICS or
necessary to ensure that ICS providers
receive fair compensation for providing
service. Further, we find that removing
a substantial number of unjustifiable
charges not only benefits consumers,
but also reduces compliance costs for
ICS providers by allowing them easily to
identify whether a particular charge is
permitted by our rules, thus reducing
the burden on them. As noted below,
however, to minimize any potential
burdens associated with ancillary
service charges, we will reevaluate these
charges to determine if adjustments are
appropriate.
5. Fees for Single-Call and Related
Services
182. Background. The record
indicates that single-call and related
services are a growing part of the ICS
market. These options, such as singlecall services, are billing arrangements
whereby an ICS provider’s collect calls
are billed through third-party billing
entities on a call-by-call basis to parties
whose carriers do not bill collect calls.
A single-call service thus may be used
for calls placed from the inmate facility
to mobile phones or a telecom service
where the called party does not have an
account, does not want to establish an
account, or does not know the party can
establish an account with the ICS
provider. Although some efficiencies
may derive from single-call and related
services, the record is replete with
evidence that some of these services are
being used in a manner to inflate
charges, and may be offered at unjust,
unreasonable, or unfair rates, and/or at
rates above our interim rate caps or rate
caps adopted in this Order. The record
also highlights substantial end-user
confusion regarding single-call services.
183. A significant problem with
single-call and related services is that
they end up being among the most
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:49 Dec 17, 2015
Jkt 238001
expensive ways to make a phone call. In
the Second FNPRM, the Commission
sought comment on the prevalence of
single-call services and whether rates
for such services are just and
reasonable.
184. There is a diversity of views in
the record on single-call and related
services. CPC believes that single-call
services should be treated as ancillary
services subject to rate caps and that
consumers must be notified of the
option to set up a prepaid account
instead. Several commenters believe
that all of these single-call and related
services should be eliminated because
they are simply an ‘‘end run’’ around
the Commission’s rate caps. The Wright
Petitioners note that any proposed rate
caps should also apply to single-call
services, along with a $3.00 funding fee.
PPI also argues that, in the alternative,
charges for single call services should be
restricted to a reasonable deposit fee,
plus a reasonable capped call fee. As the
Alabama PSC notes, ‘‘[t]he regulator’s
duty is to set fair and reasonable rates
for ICS calls.’’
185. ICSolutions notes that the singlecall or related service charge is often
$9.99 or $14.99, regardless of whether
the call lasts one minute or 10 or 15
minutes, and that these rates are 300
percent or 376 percent higher than the
effective interstate rate caps. It contends
that such calls pose a danger to
consumers, and that providers
manipulate consumers into selecting
these calling options even though less
costly call options may exist. Other
providers share ICSolutions’ concern
that single-call or related services are
used to ‘‘inflate ancillary fees’’ at the
expense of end users. CenturyLink,
ICSolutions, and NCIC, among others,
expressed concern about the use of third
parties, including unregulated
subsidiaries, to provide single-call or
related services at high fees, and about
revenue-sharing arrangements that
enable ICS providers to recoup all or a
portion of the ancillary service charge as
profit outside our rate caps.
Additionally, the Alabama PSC
analyzed these single-call services in a
jail, and found that ‘‘[a]lthough single
payment calls account for 14% of the
calls and 17% of the minutes at the
facility, they are responsible for 42% of
all the revenue generated.’’ Conversely,
GTL urges the Commission not to
regulate these services, arguing the
Commission does not have jurisdiction
to do so. Securus similarly argues that
single-call and related services should
not be considered ancillary services
because they are optional and are not
intended to be a substitute for
traditional ICS calls. Securus asserts
PO 00000
Frm 00027
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
79161
that if the Commission regulates the
rates for single-call and related services,
ICS providers will be forced to stop
offering them, and inmates and their
friends and families will have fewer
calling options by which to stay in
touch.
186. Discussion. We agree with
commenters that suggest single-call and
related services are another form of
ancillary service charges. The additional
costs stemming from single-call and
related services are ancillary to the
provision of ICS because they are
additional fees charged to consumers,
based on the consumer’s discretion and
desire to make use of such a service
because, for example they want to speak
to the incarcerated person as quickly as
possible in order to arrange their
release. We therefore believe that reform
is necessary and that it is appropriate to
address unreasonable charges. As a
result, for single call and related
services, we permit ICS providers to
charge the amount of the third-party
financial transaction (with no markup)
added to a per-minute rate no higher
than the applicable rate cap. These
reforms are necessary to ensure that
when end users decide to take
advantage of single-call and related
services, the rates for such calls comply
with the statute.
187. Unlike the ancillary service
charge caps adopted above, we do not
find that single-call and related services
are reasonably and directly related to
the provision of ICS, but are ancillary to
ICS. We believe that charges for singlecall and related services inflate the
effective price end users pay for ICS and
result in excessive compensation to
providers. Accordingly, for single-call
and related services, the Commission
will allow ICS providers to charge end
users for each single call in a manner
consistent with our approach to thirdparty financial transaction fees—i.e.,
ICS providers may charge the amount of
the third-party financial transaction
(with no markup) added to a per-minute
rate no higher than the applicable rate
cap. This approach is consistent with
our overall approach to reforming both
ICS per-minute rates and ancillary
service charges. It will ensure just and
reasonable rates for end users that are
based on actual costs incurred by ICS
providers.
188. The record supports our reforms
to fees charged for single-call and
related services. We have authority to
reform ancillary service charges and we
therefore disagree with ICS providers
that argue we lack authority. Moreover,
our approach in no way interferes with
contracts between ICS providers and
third-party payment processors or
E:\FR\FM\18DER2.SGM
18DER2
79162
Federal Register / Vol. 80, No. 243 / Friday, December 18, 2015 / Rules and Regulations
mobile phone companies because our
rule simply prevents ICS providers from
adding additional fees to the cost of
these calls. It does not dictate what fees
an ICS provider itself may choose to pay
or not pay these third parties for
services rendered.
189. We have also heard from
commenters that a major problem with
single-call and related services is that
customers are often unaware that other
payment options are available, such as
setting up an account. To help alleviate
the problem of customers continually
paying set up fees for single-call and
related service calls, we encourage
providers to make clear to consumers
that they have other payment options
available to them. This is consistent
with our discussion and analysis
regarding consumer disclosure
requirements below. We will continue
to monitor the use of such calling
arrangements and seek specific
information about them in the Further
Notice of Proposed Rulemaking
published elsewhere in this issue of the
Federal Register.
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES2
6. Taxes and Regulatory Fees
190. The record in this proceeding
indicates that ICS providers charge ICS
end users ‘‘fees under the guise of
taxes.’’ In an effort to ensure just,
reasonable and fair ICS rates, in the
Second FNPRM, the Commission asked
‘‘whether the cost of regulatory
compliance should be considered a
normal cost of doing business and as
such should be recovered through basic
ICS rates, not additional ancillary fees.’’
In response, Lattice asserts that ‘‘ICS
providers also must be permitted to
continue to collect pass-through charges
such as state and local taxes, universal
service and numbering charges, and
other federal, state and local fees.’’
191. ICS providers are permitted to
recover mandatory applicable passthrough taxes and regulatory fees, but
without any additional mark-up or fees.
The Commission has defined a
government mandated charge as
follows: ‘‘amounts that a carrier is
required to collect directly from
customers, and remit to federal, state or
local governments.’’ Non-mandated
charges are defined to be ‘‘government
authorized but discretionary fees, which
a carrier must remit pursuant to
regulatory action but over which the
carrier has discretion whether and how
to pass on the charge to the consumer.’’
Commission precedent prohibits
providers from placing a line item on a
carrier’s bill that implies a charge is
mandated by the government when it is
in fact, discretionary.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:49 Dec 17, 2015
Jkt 238001
192. We agree that the ability to
collect applicable pass-through taxes
and regulatory fees without adding a
markup is important and consistent
with precedent. However, we reiterate
that it is misleading ‘‘for carriers to state
or imply that a charge is required by the
government when it is the carriers’
business decision as to whether and
how much of such costs they choose to
recover directly from consumers
through a separate line item charge.’’ As
such, we do not permit fees or charges
beyond mandatory taxes and fees, and
authorized fees that the carrier has the
discretion to pass through to consumers
without any mark up. This will help
ensure, consistent with the goals of the
reforms adopted in this Order, that ICS
end user’s rates are just, reasonable and
fair because they are paying the cost of
the service they have chosen and any
applicable taxes or fees, and nothing
more. This approach has support in the
record, including from the Joint
Provider Proposal and Pay Tel.
7. Legal Authority
193. We reaffirm the Commission’s
finding in the 2013 Order that it has
jurisdiction over interstate ICS ancillary
service charges and further find that we
have authority to reform intrastate
ancillary service charges. The
Commission sought comment in the
Second FNPRM as to whether it is also
authorized to regulate intrastate
ancillary service charges. In response,
several commenters took the position
that section 276 of the Act authorizes
the Commission to regulate intrastate
ancillary service charges. We agree.
194. We find that the Commission has
the legal authority to adopt necessary
reforms to interstate, intrastate, and
international ancillary service charges.
In the 2013 Order, the Commission
addressed interstate charges and found
that billing and collection services
provided by a common carrier for its
own customers are subject to section
201, and are therefore, subject to
Commission regulation. The
Commission explained that it has
jurisdiction ‘‘to regulate the manner in
which a carrier bills and collects for its
own interstate offerings, because such
billing is an integral part of that carrier’s
communication service.’’ We reaffirm
that finding here. Thus, providers are on
notice that efforts to circumvent our rate
caps through artificially high ancillary
fees will not be tolerated.
195. Although ‘‘ancillary services’’ are
not defined by statute, and there is some
disagreement in the record on this
point, the dictionary meaning of the
term ‘‘ancillary’’—‘‘providing necessary
support to the primary activities or
PO 00000
Frm 00028
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
operation of an organization, institution,
industry, or system’’—is instructive.
Additionally, section 276(b)(1)(A)
specifies that any compensation plan set
forth by the Commission must ensure
that providers ‘‘are fairly compensated
for each and every completed intrastate
and interstate call . . . .’’
196. In the discussion above, we find
that we have jurisdiction over intrastate
ICS charges, pursuant to section 276 of
the Act. We also note that section 276(d)
defines ‘‘payphone service’’ as ‘‘the
provision of public or semi-public pay
telephones, the provision of inmate
telephone service in correctional
institutions, and any ancillary services.’’
Thus, we believe it is clear that
Congress provided the Commission with
authority over ICS-related ‘‘ancillary
services.’’ Based upon the plain
language of these statutory provisions
and the common definition of the term
‘‘ancillary,’’ we find that the term
‘‘ancillary services,’’ as used in section
276(d), is reasonably interpreted to
mean services that provide necessary
support for the completion of
international, interstate and intrastate
calls provided via ICS. We find that
section 276 authorizes the Commission
to regulate charges for intrastate
ancillary services, such as billing and
collection services, to the extent those
charges involve the completion of a call,
or other communications services. Such
charges are quite literally the ‘‘necessary
support’’ essential for the completion of
inmate phone calls. Indeed, often the
only purpose for establishing ICS
accounts is to fund communication with
inmates; therefore, these charges are
reasonably understood to be ancillary to
the completion of phone calls. As such,
we conclude that billing-and-collectionrelated ancillary services such as
account set up and transaction fees fall
within the Commission’s jurisdictional
authority and will be regulated in the
manner described above.
D. Periodic Review of Reforms
197. While the 2013 Order and
today’s reforms are a significant step
forward, we are committing to
continuing to review the ICS market,
including both costs and rates, to ensure
that regulation remains necessary and
that the reforms we adopt herein strike
the right balance. The reforms adopted
in this Order may facilitate changes in
the ICS market that potentially could
make it function properly and enable
the Commission to reduce regulations.
At the same time, changes in the market,
for example, may necessitate additional
modifications to the reform we adopt
today. We will incorporate lessons
learned from the prior data collection to
E:\FR\FM\18DER2.SGM
18DER2
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 80, No. 243 / Friday, December 18, 2015 / Rules and Regulations
improve quality and eliminate
anomolies. While the policies adopted
in this Order have been carefully
designed based on the record before us,
we remain dedicated to evaluating how
changing circumstances impact the
nature and scope of reform. The
Commission has the authority to take
steps to effectively monitor compliance
with this Order going forward.
198. To enable the Commission to
take further ICS reform action, identify
and track trends in the ICS market, as
well as monitor compliance with the
reforms adopted herein, we adopt a
second, one-time Mandatory Data
Collection to occur two years from
publication of Office of Management
and Budget (OMB) approval of the
information collection. We believe it is
appropriate to be able to conduct a
review of the ICS market including ICS
costs, rates and ancillary service charges
to ensure that any regulations continue
to be necessary to fulfill our statutory
objectives and to ensure that any such
reforms and rate caps reflect current
market dynamics and costs.
199. In the Second FNPRM, the
Commission sought comment on the
benefits of establishing a review
process. The Commission also sought
comment on the Wright Petitioners’
suggestion that the Commission commit
to review the interim rates adopted in
the 2013 Order. In its comments, HRDC
states generally that periodic reviews by
the Commission to evaluate the ways in
which ICS reforms impact phone rates,
ancillary service charges and
competition in the industry are
‘‘essential to ensure that the reforms
create and maintain the proper
incentives to drive ICS rates to
competitive levels.’’
200. We find that, on balance,
Petitioners’ proposal for a periodic
review of ICS data is not necessary at
this time, nor is it the best tool for
monitoring compliance with the Order.
Therefore, we establish a less onerous
requirement, which we anticipate will
provide significant benefit at minimal
cost. In lieu of the Petitioners’ proposal,
we adopt an approach similar to the one
used by the Commission in a prior
payphone order establishing the per-call
rate for payphones, in which the
Commission determined that it would
‘‘have to periodically review the costbased compensation rate in order to
ensure that it continues to ‘fairly
compensate’ PSPs and promote
payphone competition and widespread
deployment of payphones.’’ The
Commission explained that,
‘‘[e]specially when market conditions
have changed significantly, it is
incumbent upon us to reexamine
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:49 Dec 17, 2015
Jkt 238001
whether the conditions resulting in the
recent Commission-prescribed rate still
apply.’’ As with that situation, we
conclude that the Commission should
have the tools necessary to review the
reforms that we adopt in this Order, in
light of changing market conditions, to
ensure that the rates continue to be just,
reasonable, and fair. As explained
above, ancillary service charges also
significantly impact the effective rates
ICS providers charge, and should
therefore be part of this review.
201. To allow for consistent data
reporting and to prevent duplicative
filings, we direct the Bureau to develop
a template for submitting the data and
provide ICS providers with further
instructions to implement the data
collection. We direct the Bureau to
complete a review of ICS costs and rates
within one year from the date data is
submitted, and we delegate to the
Bureau authority to require an ICS
provider to submit such data as the
Bureau deems necessary to perform its
review. Information in response to the
forthcoming data collection may be filed
under the Protective Order in this
proceeding and will be treated as
confidential.
202. Several commenters have
expressed concern for the lack of
transparency regarding ICS rates and
fees. We share the concern that ICS
contracts are not sufficiently transparent
and we find adequate evidence, such as
numerous public records lawsuits, to
support HRDC’s assertion that members
of the public must ‘‘unnecessarily
expend time and money to obtain
records’’ of ICS contracts. We also
recognize evidence suggesting that the
information regarding ICS contracts and
rates that is publically available may not
be reliable. Therefore, we encourage ICS
providers and facilities to make their
contracts publicly available.
E. Harmonization With State ICS Rules
and Requirements
203. Below, we provide guidance to
ICS providers, correctional facilities and
state regulatory bodies on the effect of
the comprehensive reforms adopted
herein on ICS requirements in the states
and the Commission’s authority to
regulate these services pursuant to
section 276 of the Communications Act.
1. Background
204. In the 2013 Order, the
Commission sought comment on its
tentative conclusion that section 276
‘‘affords the Commission broad
discretion to regulate intrastate ICS rates
and practices . . . and to preempt
inconsistent state requirements.’’
Commenters’ responses were mixed.
PO 00000
Frm 00029
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
79163
The Commission then followed up by
seeking more focused comments on
issues related to preemption and
harmonization of state ICS
requirements. Several commenters
support preemption of state laws and
requirements that are inconsistent with
the federal regime, while a small
number of commenters oppose such
preemption and question our authority
to preempt state requirements related to
intrastate ICS. As discussed below, we
now adopt the tentative conclusion the
Commission first expressed in the 2013
Order, and hold that we have the
authority to preempt state requirements
that are inconsistent with the rules we
adopt in this Order. More specifically,
we conclude that a state requirement
that ICS be provided at a particular rate
that exceeds the caps we have adopted
would trigger change-in-law provisions
or require renegotiation. If for some
reason that does not occur for any
particular contract, parties can file a
petition with the Commission seeking
the appropriate relief. State rates below
our rate caps or ancillary fee caps will
not be preempted.
205. The rate caps and reforms
adopted herein should operate as a
ceiling in areas where states have not
enacted reforms. This is consistent with
Commission precedent in which it has
determined that rates at or below a
newly-enacted rate cap were not to be
changed. We strongly encourage all
states to evaluate additional measures to
reduce and eliminate site commissions
and ensure that rates for inmate calling
services are as low as possible while
still ensuring that robust security
protocols are in place. Our actions today
serve to ensure that a much-needed
default framework is in place in areas
where states have not acted to curb ICS
rates.
206. In the Second FNPRM, the
Commission sought comment on a
number of issues related to the
preemption of state regulation of ICS, as
well as the potential to harmonize state
requirements that are inconsistent with
the Commission’s comprehensive
framework for regulation of both
interstate and intrastate ICS. Among
other questions, the Commission sought
comment on its belief that it has ‘‘broad
discretion to find that a particular state
requirement, or category of state
requirements, is either consistent or
inconsistent with Commission ICS
regulations under section 276(c)’’ and to
preempt those regulations that are
inconsistent.
207. Several commenters support
preemption, urging the Commission to
establish a uniform framework for both
interstate and intrastate ICS. ICS
E:\FR\FM\18DER2.SGM
18DER2
79164
Federal Register / Vol. 80, No. 243 / Friday, December 18, 2015 / Rules and Regulations
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES2
provider Lattice, for example, argues
that ‘‘[s]ound public policy as well as
the Communications Act and FCC
precedent all support FCC reform across
all ICS.’’ Lattice contends not only that
‘‘[s]ection 276 grants the Commission
express authority to preempt state
requirements to the extent they are
inconsistent with FCC regulations,’’ but
that ‘‘preemption of state regulation is
required to fulfill the requirements of
section 276.’’ Pay Tel also argues that
the Commission has authority over
intrastate ICS, and must ‘‘preempt
inconsistent state regulations.’’
Additional commenters echo these
assertions, arguing that the Commission
has jurisdiction over both interstate and
intrastate rates and must preempt
inconsistent state requirements. Indeed,
the Wright Petitioners state that ‘‘there
is no debate that the FCC has the
authority to preempt those state
regulations that conflict with
regulations adopted in this proceeding.’’
208. Other commenters contend that
the Commission lacks the authority to
preempt state ICS requirements.
According to the Arizona Corporation
Commission (ACC), for example,
‘‘[s]ection 276 must be read in pari
materia with 47 U.S.C. 152’s reservation
of authority over intrastate matters.’’
The ACC further asserts that ‘‘the
primary purpose of section 276 was to
prevent unfair competition by
incumbent local exchange carriers
against the payphone providers [and
t]he other express purpose of this
section was to ensure that payphone
providers were fairly compensated for
all calls placed using their payphones.’’
In addition, the ACC claims that state
regulation of intrastate ICS is part of the
states’ ‘‘historic police powers’’ and
therefore should not be preempted
unless preemption ‘‘was the clear and
manifest purpose of Congress.’’
2. Discussion
209. NARUC and the ACC argue that
our authority under section 276 is
limited to interstate services, and that
our regulations must be narrowly
targeted to address concerns about
anticompetitive conduct by incumbent
local exchange carriers. We disagree.
These arguments are contradicted by the
plain language of section 276. As
explained above, the statute provides
the Commission with the authority to
regulate both interstate and intrastate
ICS. Similarly, although section 276
addresses potential discrimination by
Bell operating companies, it also
contains provisions related to other
subjects, including compensation for
‘‘payphone service providers,’’ a group
that, by definition, encompasses
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:49 Dec 17, 2015
Jkt 238001
providers ‘‘of inmate telephone service
in correctional institutions, and any
ancillary services.’’ Furthermore, we
believe that section 276’s broad mandate
stands in stark opposition to ACC’s and
NARUC’s attempts to narrowly confine
the Commission’s ICS-related
preemption authority.
210. Pay Tel urges the Commission to
preempt state-imposed intrastate rates
that are below the adopted caps, arguing
that any rates that deviate from the
Commission’s caps are ‘‘by definition,
‘inconsistent’’’ and must be preempted.
We disagree. The primary purpose of
the rate caps we adopt today is to ensure
that ICS rates are ‘‘just and reasonable’’
and do not take unfair advantage of
inmates or their families. State
requirements that result in rates below
our caps advance that purpose and there
is no credible record evidence
demonstrating or indicating that any
requirements that result in rates below
our conservative caps are so low as to
clearly deny providers fair
compensation. Evidence in the record
shows that ICS can be provided at rates
at or below $0.05 a minute. We applaud
the efforts some states have made to
lower ICS rates and hope other states
follow their lead. Our goal is affordable
rates that provide fair compensation,
and the federal framework we adopt
today is meant to serve as a backstop to
ensure rates are consistent with the
statute in absence of state action.
211. We are mindful, however, of the
fact that we also have a statutory
obligation to ensure that payphone
service providers, including ICS
providers, are ‘‘fairly compensated.’’ If
any state adopts intrastate requirements
that result in providers being unable to
receive fair compensation, providers
may either seek appropriate relief in
that state or from the Commission. We
will review the relevant state
requirements if they are brought to our
attention in a petition and will decide
at that time what, if any, remedial
actions are warranted. If any party
believes that a particular form of relief
is called for, that party should clearly
state the requested relief in a petition
and set forth the legal authority for
granting such relief. As noted above,
section 276 explicitly grants the
Commission authority to preempt state
requirements to the extent they are
inconsistent with FCC regulations.
Accordingly, if a provider is able to
demonstrate that a particular state law
or requirement is inconsistent with the
rules we adopt in this Order, we will,
consistent with section 276, preempt the
inconsistent requirement. We strongly
encourage providers to seek relief from
the relevant state entity before
PO 00000
Frm 00030
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
approaching the Commission, however.
We also note that there is no
presumption that state-mandated rates
deny fair compensation simply because
they are lower than our rate caps. To the
contrary, as noted above, we encourage
states to enact additional reforms to
inmate calling service and to drive
intrastate rates as low as possible,
consistent with the need to ensure fair
compensation, retain service quality,
and maintain adequate security.
212. Consistent with the regulatory
approach adopted herein, providers may
be able to comply with such statutory
requirements without charging rates that
exceed our rate caps. Given the absence
of clear evidence indicating whether
there are any state laws or other
requirements that, in practice, would
require providers to charge rates that
exceed our caps, we need not decide
whether any laws currently exist that
are ‘‘inconsistent’’ with our regulatory
framework. To the extent there are state
requirements, including possible
contractual requirements, that make our
rate caps onerous for a particular
provider, the affected provider may file
for preemption of the state requirement
or seek a temporary waiver of the rate
caps for the duration of any existing
contract. We note that any waiver
request should include a discussion of
the provider’s efforts to renegotiate the
subject contracts and the outcome of
such efforts. We delegate to the Bureau
the authority to rule on such petitions
and to seek additional information as
needed. We also direct the Bureau to
endeavor to complete review of any
such petitions within 90 days of the
provider submitting all information
necessary to justify a waiver.
3. Existing Contracts
213. As the Commission has
previously noted, ICS contracts
‘‘typically include change of law
provisions.’’ We expect that the new
rate caps and other requirements
adopted in this Order constitute
regulatory changes sufficient to trigger
contractual change-in-law provisions
that will allow ICS providers to void,
modify or renegotiate aspects of their
existing contracts to the extent
necessary to comply with the new rate
caps and/or to relieve the providers
from site commission payments that
would prove to be unduly onerous once
this Order takes effect. The record
regarding implementation of the 2013
interim rate caps indicates that such
changes were implemented quickly.
Indeed, the Commission has previously
highlighted the fact that the record
‘‘indicates that ICS contracts are
amended on a regular basis.’’ For
E:\FR\FM\18DER2.SGM
18DER2
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 80, No. 243 / Friday, December 18, 2015 / Rules and Regulations
instance, the record indicates that
Securus provided nine days’ notice to
facilities prior to implementing the rate
caps adopted in the 2013 Order. The
record also indicates that GTL had a
four-day transition period after
executing a new contract to serve the
state of Ohio.
214. Parties have further argued that
invoking contractual change of law
provisions and engaging in
renegotiations with correctional
facilities would materially affect ICS
providers’ ability to conduct their daily
business. Yet the Commission saw little
such impact regarding implementation
of the 2013 interim rate caps. Those rate
caps affected all interstate calls
throughout the country, much like
today’s reforms will affect calls
nationwide. Our experience with the
Commission’s previous reforms leads us
to conclude that, for ICS providers that
choose to invoke existing change of law
provisions—and subsequently to engage
in renegotiations with the facilities they
serve—any inconvenience imposed on
them in doing so will not materially
affect the providers’ ability to conduct
their day-to-day business. Finally, the
negotiations for any new or renewed
contracts can and should be informed
by the decisions in this Order, including
our adoption of new rate caps for ICS.
215. ICS providers that have entered
into contracts without change-of-law
provisions did so with full knowledge
that the Commission’s ICS proceeding
has been pending since 2012. Even so,
we encourage facilities to work with
those ICS providers during the
transition period described below which
we believe provides ample time to
renegotiate contracts, if necessary, to be
consistent with this Order. If any
provider believes it is being denied fair
compensation during the transition or
implementation of the reforms adopted
in this Order—due, for example, to the
interaction of our rate caps with the
terms of the provider’s existing service
contracts—it may file a petition seeking
a limited waiver of our new rate caps or
seek preemption of the requirement to
pay a site commission, to the extent that
it believes that such a requirement is a
state requirement and is inconsistent
with the Commission’s regulations.
Finally, negotiations for any new or
renewed contracts can and should
comply with the decisions in this Order,
including our limitation on site
commission payments and our adoption
of new rate caps.
216. We note that the contractual
provisions to which a state subjects
itself, or its subdivision, may reasonably
be subsumed within the ‘‘state
requirements’’ addressed by section
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:49 Dec 17, 2015
Jkt 238001
276(c). Therefore, if a state or a political
subdivision thereof uses a contractual
agreement as a vehicle to impose certain
requirements regarding rates or other
aspects of ICS, we would consider, on
a case-by-case, fact-specific basis,
preempting those requirements to the
extent they are ‘‘inconsistent with the
Commission’s regulations’’ as set forth
in this Order. Without deciding whether
preemption is factually or legally
warranted in any particular case, we
note that a contrary interpretation could
leave states and localities free to
undermine the Commission’s
implementation of section 276 by doing
so via a contract, rather than a state law
or regulation, which result appears to be
counter to Congress’s objectives in
enacting section 276(c). As the
Commission has noted in this very
proceeding, ‘‘agreements cannot
supersede the Commission’s authority
to ensure that the rates paid by
individuals who are not parties to those
agreements are fair, just and
reasonable.’’ To the extent ICS providers
require waiver relief, they may take
advantage of the procedures described
below.
F. Waivers of Rules Adopted in This
Order
217. In the 2013 Order, the
Commission held that an ICS provider
that ‘‘believes that it has cost-based rates
for ICS that exceed our interim rate
caps’’ may file a petition for waiver for
good cause. The 2013 Order also
confirmed that the Commission’s
standard waiver process applies to ICS
providers. The Commission delegated to
the Bureau the authority to approve or
deny waiver requests. The Commission
articulated the following factors that the
Bureau could consider in reviewing a
waiver request: Costs directly related to
the provision of interstate ICS and
ancillary services; demand levels and
trends; a reasonable allocation of
common costs; and general and
administrative cost data. The
Commission also noted that, because the
adopted interim interstate rate caps
were set at conservative levels, it
expected that petitions for waiver
‘‘would account for extraordinary
circumstances.’’ Additionally, the
Commission held that, for ‘‘substantive
and administrative reasons,’’ waiver
petitions would be evaluated at the
holding company level. The Bureau
processed three requests for waiver of
the interim interstate rate caps following
this guidance and granted a temporary
waiver to one provider.
218. In the Second FNPRM, the
Commission sought comment on the
waiver process detailed in the 2013
PO 00000
Frm 00031
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
79165
Order. Several commenters object to the
use of this waiver process to address
concerns about the sufficiency of the
rate caps. Some ICS providers ask that
we review waiver petitions on a facilityby-facility basis in order to review
locations where the costs of service
exceed the rate caps. One commenter
requests an expedited waiver process to
allow the adoption of products or
services involving costs paid to a third
party, such as those involving a software
agreement or new security feature.
Commenters also suggest that the
Bureau issue a blanket waiver excluding
juvenile detention centers, secure
mental health facilities, and jails with
small populations, from our rate caps.
219. We have relied on the Mandatory
Data Collection in establishing the rate
caps adopted above. For the reasons
previously given, we believe our rate
caps are more than sufficient to allow
carriers to receive fair compensation.
We agree with the Petitioners that a
tiered rate cap approach, as adopted
herein, will reduce the need for waivers.
We recognize, however, that we cannot
foreclose the possibility that in certain
limited instances, our rate caps may not
be sufficient for certain providers. For
those instances, we reaffirm the waiver
standard for ICS providers adopted in
the 2013 Order and delegate to the
Bureau the authority to rule on such
waivers. Accordingly, an ICS provider
that believes the rate caps for interstate
and intrastate ICS do not allow for fair
compensation may seek a waiver
pursuant to the guidance articulated in
the 2013 Order. ICS provider waiver
petitions may be accorded confidential
treatment to the extent consistent with
rule 0.459. We direct the Bureau to
endeavor act to on such waivers within
90 days of the provider submitting all
information necessary to justify a
waiver. As the Commission previously
stated, waiver petitions should be filed
at the holding-company level. We
believe that this approach best captures
the way the majority of the ICS market
functions; specifically that ICS
providers serve multiple facilities
utilizing centralized infrastructure, thus
spreading related costs across their
correctional facility customer base
whenever possible. Furthermore, as
described in the 2013 Order, providers
will be expected to provide data
showing why they are unable to meet
their costs under the applicable rate
caps. We reiterate that ‘‘unless and until
a waiver is granted, an ICS provider may
not charge rates above the [applicable]
rate cap and must comply with all
aspects of this Order . . . .’’ However,
consistent with Commission precedent,
E:\FR\FM\18DER2.SGM
18DER2
79166
Federal Register / Vol. 80, No. 243 / Friday, December 18, 2015 / Rules and Regulations
exigent circumstances may warrant that
the Bureau provide interim relief during
the pendency of its review of a waiver
request.
220. We also conclude that there is
insufficient evidence available at this
time to support a blanket waiver to
providers incurring third-party
technology costs or serving high-cost
facilities. The Bureau will consider
waiver petitions, including those from
providers claiming to serve high-cost
facilities, and evaluate the details
specific to such petitions on a case-bycase basis.
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES2
G. Disability Access to ICS
1. Background
221. In the 2012 NPRM, the
Commission noted that ‘‘there is
evidence in the record to indicate that
inmates with hearing disabilities may
not have access to ICS at reasonable
rates using TTYs [text telephones].’’
Specifically, the Commission cited
evidence that ‘‘deaf and hard of hearing
inmates who use TTYs have to pay more
than their hearing counterparts’’
because ‘‘the average length of a
telephone conversation using a TTY is
approximately four times longer than a
voice telephone conversation.’’ In light
of this record, the Commission sought
comment about the ICS access available
to deaf and hard of hearing inmates and
about the rates such inmates paid for
ICS.
222. In the 2013 Order, the
Commission clarified that ICS providers
may not collect additional charges for
calls made through any type of
telecommunications relay service (TRS).
In the Second FNPRM that accompanied
the 2013 Order, the Commission also
noted commenters’ assertions that TTY
calls take ‘‘at least three to four times
longer than voice-to-voice conversations
to deliver the same conversational
content.’’ The Commission, therefore,
tentatively concluded that per-minute
ICS rates for TTY calls should be 25
percent of the rate for standard ICS
calls, and sought comment on this
proposal. In addition, the Commission
sought comment on a number of other
issues related to ICS for inmates who are
deaf and hard of hearing, including: (1)
Whether and how to discount the perminute rate for ICS calls placed using
TTY; (2) whether action is required to
ensure that ICS providers do not deny
access to TRS by blocking calls to 711
and/or state established TRS access
numbers; (3) the need for ICS providers
to receive complaints on TRS and file
reports on those complaints with the
Commission; and (4) actions the
Commission can take to promote the
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:49 Dec 17, 2015
Jkt 238001
availability and use of video relay
service (VRS) and other assistive
technologies in prisons.
223. The Commission asked
additional questions about accessible
ICS in the Second FNPRM. Specifically,
the Commission sought comment on the
following: (1) The actual relative length
of TTY-to-TTY and TTY-to-voice calls
as compared to voice-to-voice calls; (2)
the claim that no ICS provider charges
for voice-to-TTY or TTY-to-voice calls
because ‘‘the ‘interexchange company
holding the [state] TRS contract carries
the call to the called party,’ ’’ and if true,
whether the final reduced ICS rates for
TTY calls should only apply to TTY-toTTY calls; (3) whether AT&T and other
entities that provide TRS are providing
ICS for TRS calls placed by inmates; (4)
how the Commission’s relay service
registration requirements can be met in
a correctional facility setting where the
equipment is handled by several users;
and (5) the availability of and security
concerns relating to devices used with
newer technologies, such as
videophones used for VRS and point-topoint video communications, devices
used for IP CTS, and devices used for IP
Relay.
224. Since 2012, when the
Commission first sought comment on
access to ICS for inmates who are deaf
or hard of hearing, the Commission has
continued to receive filings expressing
concern about these prisoners’ lack of
access to telephone services that are
functionally equivalent to the services
available to users of traditional voice
services. The Washington Lawyers’
Committee (WLC), for example, claims
that correctional facilities often fail to
make TRS available to inmates.
Similarly, Helping Educate to Advance
the Rights of the Deaf (HEARD) asserts
that ‘‘deaf prisoners in several states
have had no telecommunications access
for several years, while deaf detainees
often spend their entire time in jail with
no telecommunication.’’ According to
the Rosen Bien Galvan & Grunfeld
(RBGG) law firm, its clients ‘‘routinely
report that their access even to outdated
and disfavored [TTYs], particularly in
county jail facilities, is limited to
nonexistent and that their ability to
communicate with loved ones and
attorneys is thereby impaired.’’ RBGG
further asserts that, even when
correctional facilities have TTYs, ‘‘they
are often not actually available to our
clients because they are broken, because
staff does not know they exist, or
because staff does not know how to use
the machines.’’
225. In response to the Second
FNPRM, Securus and GTL contend that
correctional facilities, not the ICS
PO 00000
Frm 00032
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
providers, ‘‘set correction facility policy
as to the amount of access that hearingimpaired inmates (or any inmates) have
to telecommunications services.’’ GTL
also asserts that ‘‘disability access
concerns are being addressed by the
industry’’ and that GTL’s inmate calling
services and the rates for those services
are ‘‘fully compliant with the
requirements of the Americans with
Disabilities Act (ADA), the
Communications Act of 1934, as
amended, and current Commission
requirements.’’
2. Discussion
226. Functionally Equivalent Access.
We now take measures to address the
various concerns and ongoing reports
regarding the lack of equal telephone
access by inmates. As an initial matter,
we note that this proceeding has
generally referred to individuals who
are ‘‘deaf and hard of hearing,’’ in
discussing accessibility matters.
Because inmates who are deaf-blind or
have speech disabilities also use TRS,
they, too, have the same or similar
policy concerns as inmates who are deaf
or hard of hearing. Accordingly, we will
now refer more generally to inmates
with ‘‘communication disabilities’’
when discussing these accessibility
issues. Additionally, we note that while
our focus here is primarily on calls that
are made by inmates with these
disabilities, some of the policies we
adopt requiring access to TRS will also
benefit inmates who need to place calls
to people with such disabilities.
227. Section 225 of the Act requires
every common carrier that provides
voice services to offer access to TRS
within their service areas. Accordingly,
all common carriers must make
available, or ensure the availability, to
their customers of those types of TRS
that the Commission has required to be
mandatory services provided to the
public. At present, the Commission
mandates two forms of TRS: TTY-based
TRS and speech-to-speech (STS), both
of which are provided over the PSTN.
We remind ICS providers of their
obligations to ensure the availability
and provision of these forms of TRS.
Consistent with these obligations, ICS
providers also may not block calls to
711, a short form dialing code that is
used to access TRS provided by staterun TRS programs.
228. We note that several parties have
requested that the Commission require
correctional facilities to provide more
‘‘modern’’ forms of TRS as well, along
with the equipment needed to access
those services. These parties assert that
TTYs are largely outdated and that
videophones and captioned telephones
E:\FR\FM\18DER2.SGM
18DER2
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 80, No. 243 / Friday, December 18, 2015 / Rules and Regulations
are the standard modes of
communication for people with
communication disabilities. For
example, RBGG urges the Commission’s
‘‘active intervention’’ to encourage
facilities to adopt modern
communications technologies, such as
videophones. Similarly, the National
Association of the Deaf (NAD) asserts
that ‘‘correctional facilities should be
required to install and provide access to
the telecommunications equipment
required by deaf and hard of hearing
inmates—whether it’s a TTY,
videophone, captioned telephone, or
even an amplified telephone or one that
is amplified and has large buttons.’’
229. The Communications Act
requires TRS to be provided ‘‘in a
manner that is functionally equivalent
to the ability of a hearing individual’’ to
use conventional voice telephone
services. We agree with commenters
that limiting all inmates with
communication disabilities to one form
of TRS, particularly what many view as
an outdated form of TRS that relies on
TTY usage, may result in
communication that is not functionally
equivalent to the ability of a hearing
individual to communicate by
telephone. However, as noted above, at
this time, only two forms of TRS, TTYbased TRS and STS, are mandated
services for all common carriers. While
the Commission authorizes
compensation from the Interstate TRS
Fund for VRS, IP Relay, and both PSTNbased CTS and IP CTS, it does not
mandate that these types of services be
provided by any common carrier at this
time. Accordingly, while we are only
able to require ICS providers to make
TTY-based TRS and STS available to
inmates with communication
disabilities, or to inmates who
communicate by telephone with users of
these services at this time, we strongly
encourage correctional facilities to work
with ICS providers to offer these other
forms of TRS.
230. Several inmates with
communications disabilities that have
commented in the record note that in
some instances, using a
Telecommunication Device for the Deaf
(TDD) is unsatisfactory because ‘‘[o]ur
family members and friends who are
deaf, are no longer using the obsolete
TDD system.’’ We reaffirm our existing
policy of strongly encouraging
correctional facilities to provide inmates
with communication disabilities with
access to TTYs, as well as equipment
used for advanced forms of TRS, such
as videophones and captioned
telephones. In addition, we strongly
encourage correctional facilities to
comply with obligations that may exist
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:49 Dec 17, 2015
Jkt 238001
under other federal laws, including Title
II of the ADA, which require the
provision of services to inmates with
disabilities that are as effective as those
provided to other inmates. Access to
more advanced forms of TRS, including
VRS, IP Relay, CTS, and IP CTS, may be
necessary to ensure equally effective
telephone services for these inmates. We
recognize that some facilities have
already begun providing access to
alternative forms of TRS, often as the
result of litigation brought under these
other statutes. We strongly encourage
other facilities to continue this trend
voluntarily, without the need for further
litigation. The Commission will monitor
the implementation and access to TRS
in correctional institutions and may take
additional action if inmates with
communications disabilities continue to
lack access to functionally equivalent
service.
231. Rates. Several commenters have
also expressed concern about the costs
inmates with communication
disabilities incur when they use TTYs.
HEARD, for example, asserts that TTY
calls are ‘‘at least four times slower than
voice-to-voice conversations’’ and that
‘‘this time estimation does not account
for varied literacy levels of users;
‘garbled’ transmissions that frequently
occur in loud settings or with
incompatible newer telephone
technology; or the time required to
connect to the operator, and
subsequently to the party being called,
among other things.’’ One commenter
describes his experience as an inmate
with communications disabilities:
[a]fter you give the relay operator your name
for the collect call the relay operator put[s]
you back on hold once again to see if charges
will be accepted by the party at the other end
of your call. This process takes at least 5 to
8 minutes. This time is part of the 15-minute
time limit that the Department of Corrections
has on their timers for each call. Now keep
in mind that a regular call costs a total of
about $2 but the relay service had a $3.62
hook up fee, then so much per minute after
that so you only get 5 to 7 min. and you have
to call back and repeat this process.
232. Given the differences between
TTY and traditional voice service,
several commenters argue that TTY
users should be charged a discounted
rate for ICS calls. The Prison Law Office,
for example, has argued that if the
Commission does not take into account
the relatively slow speeds of TTY-based
conversations, it will be ‘‘in effect
placing a surcharge on deaf prisoners.’’
The Commission itself tentatively
concluded in the 2013 Order that the
per-minute ICS rate for TTY calls
should be set at 25 percent of the safe
harbor rate of $0.12/minute for debit/
PO 00000
Frm 00033
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
79167
prepaid calls and $0.14/minute for
collect calls.
233. Neither ICS providers, nor any
other commenters, dispute arguments
that TTY calls are longer, and therefore
more expensive to consumers than nonTTY calls. Instead, Securus merely
contends that it receives no additional
compensation for this type of call above
its tariffed rate. GTL, for its part,
generally asserts that its ICS and
associated rates are ‘‘fully compliant
with the requirements of the Americans
with Disabilities Act, the
Communications Act of 1934, as
amended, and current Commission
requirements.’’
234. We find that the record
overwhelmingly supports the
conclusion that TTY calls take
significantly longer than voice
conversations, due to factors that
include the longer time it takes the TTY
user to type—rather than speak—his or
her part of the conversation; the time
delays that occur while the text is
transmitted; and the technical
difficulties that appear to affect TTY
calls disproportionately compared to
voice calls. TTY calls through TRS can
take even longer than calls between two
TTY users, because of the need for such
calls to be set up before the
communications assistant can connect
the TTY user to the voice telephone
user, and the need for the
communications assistant to transcribe
the spoken part of the call and relay it
to the TTY user.
235. Given that there does not appear
to be any dispute in the record over
whether TTY calls take longer to
transact than voice calls involving
similar content, the question remains
whether inmates with communication
disabilities (or their families) should be
required to pay more for ICS calls than
their hearing counterparts simply
because they need to rely on TTYs to
communicate with their friends and
relatives. As explained below, we find
that it would be unfairly discriminatory
to require TTY users to pay more per
call than users of traditional voice
telephone equipment.
236. In the 2013 Order, the
Commission clarified that it would be
inconsistent with section 225 of the Act
for ICS providers to collect ‘‘additional
charges’’ (i.e., charges in excess of those
charged by the ICS provider for
functionally equivalent voice
communications service) for calls made
through any type of telecommunications
relay service. The 2013 Order, however,
did not address the relevance of section
276 to ICS provider charges for TRS
calls. Section 276, which requires the
Commission to ensure that ICS
E:\FR\FM\18DER2.SGM
18DER2
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES2
79168
Federal Register / Vol. 80, No. 243 / Friday, December 18, 2015 / Rules and Regulations
providers ‘‘are fairly compensated for
each and every completed intrastate and
interstate call,’’ also states that TRS calls
‘‘shall not be subject to such
compensation.’’ Thus, we believe it is
reasonable for the Commission to
interpret 276(b)(1)(A) to mean that TRS
calls are not subject to the per-call
compensation framework adopted
herein. Specifically, section 276
exempts both emergency calls and TRS
calls from the fair compensation
mandate. The exemption of emergency
calls means that providers may not
charge for emergency calls. We believe
it is reasonable to interpret the pairing
of TRS with emergency calls as an
indication that Congress also intended
TRS calls be provided for no charge.
Therefore, we prohibit ICS providers
from assessing charges for ICS calls
between a TTY device and a traditional
telephone.
237. As for TTY-to-TTY calls, we find
that, because such calls, by their nature,
are of longer duration than voice calls,
and because inmates with
communication disabilities do not have
the alternative of placing voice calls, it
would be unfairly discriminatory to
require TTY users to pay more per call
than users of traditional voice telephone
equipment. This finding is compelled
not only by the evidence in the record,
but also by the language of the relevant
statutory provision. Section 276 requires
the Commission to establish a ‘‘per call
compensation plan’’ to ensure that
payphone providers, including ICS
providers, are fairly compensated for
‘‘each and every . . . call.’’ Such percall compensation must be ‘‘fair’’ not
only to the provider but also to the party
paying for the call. Because of the
significantly longer time that is
necessarily consumed by TTY calls—as
compared to the duration of voice
telephone ICS calls—we conclude that,
to ensure fair compensation on a percall basis, ICS providers should offer
TTY calls at lower per-minute rates than
are charged for voice calls, even if such
lower rates do not provide the level of
per-minute compensation determined to
be fair for voice telephone calls in the
‘‘per call compensation plan.’’ We reach
this decision because of the per-call
discrimination that would result were
we to set the same rates for both types
of calls.
238. Accordingly, for the reasons
described above, we require that the
rates charged by ICS providers for TTYto-TTY calls be no more than 25 percent
of the rates the providers charge for
traditional inmate calling services. We
recognize that this discounted rate may
not represent the same level of
compensation that is provided for voice
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:49 Dec 17, 2015
Jkt 238001
telephone calls carried over the same
networks, but we have considered any
additional costs that might be incurred
by providers in setting the rate caps for
ICS and concluded that there is enough
room within the general rate caps to
ensure the providers are still fairly
compensated. Thus, ICS providers can
expect to recover the cost of the TTY
discount through the rates they charge
other users, who account for the vast
majority of ICS calls.
239. In setting the mandatory
discount for ICS calls involving TTYs,
we are cognizant of Securus’ claim that
it cannot track TTY calls separately
from other ICS calls and that any type
of TRS-related billing requirement
‘‘would be extremely time-consuming
and burdensome.’’ If Securus, or any
other ICS provider, finds it too
burdensome to track TTY calls and bill
customers the discounted rate for those
calls, it may opt to provide TTY-to-TTY
calling for free. We expect the cost of
forgoing the discounted fees for the
relatively small number of TTY users of
ICS will be nominal and that providers
will be able to recover those costs
through the ‘‘cushion’’ we have built
into our rate caps. We find that the
benefit to inmates that use TTY and TRS
technologies outweighs any nominal
costs to ICS providers. Finally, we note
that facilities and ICS providers can
avoid costs related to TRS calls by
allowing inmates to use IP-based forms
of TRS, such as VRS, IP Relay and IP
CTS. However, the record indicates that
‘‘only a handful of prisons are equipped
with videophones (e.g., Vermont,
Virginia, and Wisconsin) and no prison
or jail is known to have installed
captioned telephones, many using
security as an excuse for
discrimination.’’ These calls would not
require the services of an ICS provider
and would be provided free of charge to
both the user and to the facility.
240. Disability-Access Related
Reporting. In discussing ICS disability
access issues in the 2013 Order, the
Commission asked whether ICS
providers should be required to collect
and report: ‘‘(i) Data on TRS usage via
ICS, and (ii) complaints from
individuals that access TRS via ICS.’’
The Commission also sought comment
‘‘on the benefits and burdens, including
on small entities, of imposing these
reporting requirements.’’
241. In the Second FNPRM, the
Commission again sought comment on
possible recordkeeping and reporting
requirements specific to accessible ICS.
Specifically, the Commission asked if
‘‘ICS providers [should] be required to
report to the Commission the number of
disability-related calls they provide, the
PO 00000
Frm 00034
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
number of problems they experience
with such calls, or related complaints
they receive?’’ In response, the NAD
asserts that the Commission should
require ‘‘complaints, technical
problems, how much
telecommunications access is provided
as compared to non-deaf or hard of
hearing inmates, and whether there is
access to modern telecommunications
equipment.’’ HEARD asserts that ‘‘[t]he
Commission can generate a genuine
sense of accountability simply by
requiring ICS providers to collect and
report data on calls made using relay
service, especially if prisoners and
family members are paying for the
service.’’ More specifically, HEARD
suggests that, pursuant to the
Commission’s existing consumer
complaint procedures, correctional
facilities should be required to report
how long they have been without relay
service or access, and if a recent change
in the ICS provider preceded the
problem.
242. Securus counters that ‘‘tracking
of TTY is not possible’’ and that culling
out calls would require Securus ‘‘to
write a new computer application for its
billing system’’ and ‘‘establish ‘separate
databases at each correctional facility to
identify inmates that may use a TTY
device or call friends or family that
require the use of a TTY or similar
device.’ ’’ Securus further asserts that
this difficulty is ‘‘compounded for any
facility that does not use Prison
Identification Numbers in association
with its inmate telephone system.’’
Securus asserts generally that any type
of TRS-related billing or call
recordkeeping requirement ‘‘would be
extremely time-consuming and
burdensome.’’
243. GTL separately asserts that the
new technologies it is introducing,
which are ‘‘better categorized as
advanced communications services
(ACS), enhanced services, or simply
new technologies’’ are already subject to
certain disability access requirements,
including recordkeeping and reporting
requirements. GTL is specifically
referring to rule 14.31, which requires
ACS providers discontinuing a product
or service to create and keep records (for
a two year period) relating to: (1) Their
efforts to consult with individuals with
disabilities; (2) the accessibility features
of their products and services; and (3)
the compatibility of their products and
services with peripheral devices or
specialized customer premise
equipment commonly used to help
individuals with disabilities achieve
access. Additionally, ACS providers
must file an annual compliance
certificate with the Commission.
E:\FR\FM\18DER2.SGM
18DER2
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 80, No. 243 / Friday, December 18, 2015 / Rules and Regulations
Finally, ACS providers facing formal or
informal accessibility complaints must
produce responsive records to the
Commission upon request.
244. After reviewing the record, we
adopt the reporting requirements
proposed by HEARD and supported by
NAD. Specifically, we require all ICS
providers to include in the Annual
Reporting and Certification filing
described below: (1) The number of
disability-related calls they provided;
(2) the number of dropped disabilityrelated calls they experienced; and (3)
the number of complaints they received
related to access to ICS by TTY and TRS
users, e.g., dropped calls, poor call
quality and the number of incidences of
each. We agree with HEARD that these
reporting requirements will foster
accountability on the part of ICS
providers. We believe these reporting
requirements will encourage providers
to actively address problems affecting
users’ ability to access TRS (including
TTY) via ICS. Moreover, the reports will
give the Commission the information
needed to assess ICS providers’
compliance with the requirements
adopted herein, as well as those
imposed by section 225, including the
statutory requirement that individuals
with communications disabilities must
be able to engage in communication by
wire or radio ‘‘in a manner that is
functionally equivalent to the ability of
a hearing individual who does not have
a speech disability,’’ as well as the
requirement that TRS be provided ‘‘in
the most efficient manner.’’
245. Securus’ main objection to the
reporting requirements appears to be
related solely to the difficulty of
tracking TRS calls. But the record
indicates that TRS calls make up only
a small portion of ICS calls. Moreover,
TTY-based TRS calls require specialized
equipment and/or require calling a
designated number such as 711. Either
scenario should facilitate tracking TTYbased TRS calls. For instance, it should
not be difficult to track a relatively
small number of calls made from
specialized equipment located in a
correctional facility. Moreover, any
burdens associated with providing
limited reporting on these calls are far
outweighed by the benefits such
reporting will offer in terms of greater
transparency and heightened
accountability on the part of ICS
providers. For example, our reporting
requirements will facilitate monitoring
of issues related to TRS calls, encourage
greater engagement by the advocacy
community, and provide the
Commission the basis to take further
action, if necessary, to improve inmates’
access to TRS.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:49 Dec 17, 2015
Jkt 238001
246. We further address concerns
regarding the burdensomeness of our
reporting requirements by establishing a
safe harbor that will allow ICS providers
to avoid any reporting obligations if
certain conditions are met. Specifically,
if an ICS provider either (1) operates in
a facility that allows the offering of
additional forms of TRS beyond those
we currently mandate or (2) has not
received any complaints related to TRS
calls, then it will not have to include
any TRS-related reporting in the Annual
Report detailed below, provided that it
includes a certification from an officer
of the company stating which prong(s)
of the safe harbor it has met. If the
facility an ICS provider serves either
ceases allowing additional forms of TRS
beyond those we mandate or the ICS
provider begins to receive TRS-related
complaints, however, it must include all
required TRS reporting information in
its next Annual Report. We note that a
report that includes the number of TRS
calls provides important context for
determining whether the number of
complaints or dropped calls reported by
a provider is problematic. We believe
that allowing these safe harbors will
provide equal or superior benefits over
the reporting requirements because if
taken advantage of they help mitigate
ICS providers’ concerns over the
burdens associated with reporting
(although we believe these burdens are
minimal), and will help drive the
adoption of more modern forms of TRS
by correctional facilities, which helps
further the deployment of ICS as well as
helps maintain or increase contact
between more incarcerated persons and
the outside world.
247. Cost-Benefit Analysis. We find
that the reporting and recordkeeping
requirements related to disability-access
ICS calling adopted in this Order are not
overly burdensome. Parties have
complained that the disability access
communications within correctional
facilities are not priced at rates that are
just, reasonable, and fair, and that
Commission intervention is necessary.
248. As discussed above, we conclude
that these recordkeeping requirements
are necessary to foster accountability on
the part of ICS providers, and will
encourage providers to address
problems limiting users’ ability to
access TRS (including TTY) via ICS.
Further, the reporting requirements will
give us the information we need to
assess ICS providers’ compliance with
the requirements adopted herein, as
well as those imposed by section 225.
249. We find unpersuasive the
objections raised to the reporting
requirements. Reporting the number of
problems and complaints associated
PO 00000
Frm 00035
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
79169
with TRS calls does not seem unduly
burdensome. TRS calls make up only a
small portion of ICS calls. Moreover, as
noted above, TTY-based calls require
specialized equipment and/or require
calls to a designated number, such as
711; either scenario should allow for
ease of tracking. Moreover, any burdens
associated with providing limited
reporting on these calls are far
outweighed by the benefits such
reporting will offer in terms of greater
transparency and heightened
accountability on the part of ICS
providers. We further mitigate any
potential burden from our reporting
requirements by establishing safe
harbors that allow ICS providers to
avoid any reporting obligations if
certain conditions are met, as discussed
more fully above.
H. Section 276 Is Technology Neutral
250. We confirm the findings in the
2013 Order that section 276, by its
terms, is technology neutral with
respect to inmate calling services. As
such, our rules adopted herein apply to
ICS regardless of the technology used to
deliver the service. Therefore, if a
particular service meets the relevant
definition in our rules, then it is a form
of ICS that was subject to our interim
rules and that is subject to the rules we
adopt today. The nomenclature used to
describe a service is not dispositive of
whether the service is or is not ICS.
Whether any particular service meets
those definitions requires a fact-specific
inquiry that we may adjudicate if
necessary. (We note that our definition
of ‘‘inmate telephone’’ is broad and does
not inherently rule out advanced
services, and that the burden is on the
provider in the first instance to
determine whether it is providing ICS,
and if it is not certain, to seek guidance
from the Commission, for example in
the form of a Declaratory Ruling.)
I. Transition and Existing Contracts
251. In establishing the transition, we
balance the critical goal of providing
necessary relief to consumers from
unreasonably high ICS rates while
remaining mindful of the potential
impact on ICS providers and facilities to
ensure a smooth transition to implement
the new reforms. In designing our
transition for this Order, we build on
the lessons learned from implementing
the 2013 ICS reforms. The record does
not indicate that providers experienced
difficulties implementing the rate caps
within 90 days after the 2013 Order’s
publication in the Federal Register. For
example, the record shows that one
provider sent a one-page letter to its
customers informing them of the rate
E:\FR\FM\18DER2.SGM
18DER2
79170
Federal Register / Vol. 80, No. 243 / Friday, December 18, 2015 / Rules and Regulations
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES2
changes to be implemented as a result
of the Commission’s 2013 Order. The
letter provided nine days’ notice before
rates changed. While we find that a
multi-year transition period for new rate
caps is unnecessary, we recognize that
the new rate caps and ancillary service
charge framework adopted in this Order
may require some adjustment time for
ICS providers and facilities.
Accordingly, the reforms adopted in this
Order will become effective March 17,
2016 for prisons and June 20, 2016 for
jails.
252. This transition period reflects a
careful balancing of the important goal
of expediting relief to end users while
allowing the necessary time to prepare
for any impact our new rules may have
on ICS providers and correctional
institutions. In adopting the transition,
we note as a threshold matter that the
issue of ICS reform has been pending for
years and, with the substantial progress
made in recent years through the 2013
Order and Second FNPRM, ICS
providers and facilities have been on
notice that the Commission may reform
ICS. With that consideration in mind,
we transition to our new rules March
17, 2016 for prisons and June 20, 2016
for jails. Below we also discuss the
effect of our adopted reforms on existing
ICS contracts.
1. Transition Proposals in the Record
253. In the Second FNPRM, the
Commission sought comment on a
variety of transition paths for the new
rules and encouraged commenters
advocating for a transition to identify
the appropriate transition framework
and the justifications for doing so. For
example, the ICS providers that
submitted the Joint Provider Proposal
suggested that ‘‘[t]he new rate caps
should become effective 90 days after
adoption, along with any site
commission reductions and ancillary fee
changes outlined below.’’ They further
asserted that ‘‘[t]his period for
implementation should ensure ICS
providers and correctional facilities
have adequate time to implement the
new rate caps and any corresponding
reductions in site commissions,
including any contract amendments or
adjustments that may be necessary.’’ Pay
Tel suggested a 90-day, after final order
publication transition period for
transaction fees, third-party money
transfer service fees, and ancillary fees
and an 18-month transition period for
jail and prison rate caps. In the Second
FNPRM the Commission also
specifically sought comment on the 90day delayed effective date we
implemented in the 2013 Order as well
as a two year transition.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:49 Dec 17, 2015
Jkt 238001
254. In response to the Second
FNPRM, many interested parties
submitted detailed comments
explaining how the Commission should
structure the transition to new rules for
ICS rates. Commenters advocated for a
variety of transition period lengths and
the responses varied depending on the
type of fee being transitioned. Some
commenters suggested that all of the
new rate caps, ancillary service charges,
and other charges should be
transitioned together. For example, GTL
explained that ‘‘[i]t is unlikely that the
Commission’s goal of achieving marketbased ICS rates will occur without
simultaneous Commission action to
establish backstop rate caps for all ICS
rates, to transition site commissions to
admin-support payments, and to define
industry-wide ancillary service charges
and fee caps.’’ We took such arguments
into consideration in designing our
transition.
255. At the other end of the spectrum,
commenters advocating for a longer
transition contend that longer
transitions are necessary to ensure that
correctional authorities and ICS
providers can plan for the new
regulatory regime. As discussed above,
facilities have received certain
inducements, such as site commissions,
from ICS providers for selecting them to
be the sole provider of ICS in their
facilities. These commissions have been
used for a variety of purposes, some of
which are wholly unrelated to the
provision of ICS to inmates and their
families. We acknowledge that our
adopted rules and requirements may
affect facility budgets, and we want to
ensure that those facilities have time to
account for disturbances to their
budgets, which is why we are not
adopting an immediate transition.
256. Proponents of the shorter length
transitions note that ICS providers and
facilities have been on notice of
upcoming changes and have
successfully adjusted quickly to new
rules in the past. For example, NJAID
and NYU IRC explain that ‘‘[i]n New
Jersey and around the country, states
and localities were able to implement
the 2013 Order within ninety days.
Moreover, these governments have been
on notice since the issuance of the First
FNPRM in 2013.’’ Commenters
advocating for shorter length transitions
expressed confidence that 90 days was
sufficient time to implement caps and
would be the timeliest option. Indeed,
some parties argued that no more than
60 days are necessary to complete the
transition. Conversely, others worry that
abbreviated transitions, such as 90-day
transitions, will not be feasible for
facilities to implement. However, other
PO 00000
Frm 00036
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
commenters point out that ‘‘[a]lmost
every ICS contract has a provision for
renegotiation due to changes in the
regulatory environment, so no one year
grace period should be required for
implementation of rates and fees.’’
CenturyLink is concerned that a 90-day
transition is not ‘‘realistic,’’ and
advocates for a substantially longer
transition period. NSA argues that a 90day transition is not sufficient for jails,
in particular. NSA notes that the sheer
number of contracts to be renegotiated
would require additional time to
complete, specifically noting that there
are ‘‘over 2000 jails in the country and
only a ‘‘handful of ICS providers.’’
Thus, NSA explains, each ICS provider
would have to renegotiate ‘‘potentially
hundreds of contracts with Sheriffs and
jails in a 90-day period.’’ According to
NSA, 90 days is not enough time to
allow providers to negotiate all of these
contracts and for those contracts to be
approved by the relevant authorities.
These concerns are echoed by Praeses
and others. We agree that these parties
raise valid concerns regarding the time
needed to transition all of the country’s
jails to the new rate regime.
Accordingly, we adopt a six-month
transition period for jails, in order to
give providers and jails enough time to
negotiate (or renegotiate) contracts to
the extent necessary to comply with all
of the rules adopted herein. We do not
believe an extended transition is
necessary for prisons to obtain new or
revised contracts, however. There are far
fewer prisons/departments of correction
than jails (typically one per state) and
providers are likely to prioritize
negotiations with prisons over
negotiations with jails, particularly
given that prisons tend to house much
larger inmate populations and generate
significantly more ICS revenues than
jails. Moreover, according to the record
more than 10 prison systems already
have rates at or below our rate caps.
Therefore, we adopt a 90-day transition
period for prisons.
2. Implementation of Reforms and
Transition Periods
257. The record reflects commenters
advocating for immediate transitions
and also for transition periods ranging
from 90 days to up to three or four
years. We find the arguments for a
shorter transition period to be the most
persuasive. The immediate transition
and long transition options are
impractical. For example, proponents of
an immediate transition generally
explained that longer transition periods
are not necessary and would only serve
to delay relief from quickly reaching
inmates and their families. Despite such
E:\FR\FM\18DER2.SGM
18DER2
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 80, No. 243 / Friday, December 18, 2015 / Rules and Regulations
arguments, we think that the reforms
adopted in this Order warrant providing
some amount of time to ensure a smooth
transition for end users, providers, and
facilities.
258. As explained above, the record
clearly shows that charges for ancillary
services have increased since the 2013
Order. This highlights that ICS
providers have the incentive and ability
to increase ancillary service charges
absent reform, which could have the
effect of frustrating the Commission’s
and Congress’s policy goals by
undermining the rate caps we adopt.
While we have received substantial
comment in the record about the
challenges associated with transitioning
for our site commission action and rate
caps, the record lacks explanation as to
why an immediate transition for
ancillary service charges would be
burdensome for ICS providers. As such,
we find that transitioning ancillary
service charges on March 17, 2016 for
prisons and June 20, 2016 for jails is
appropriate because it will provide
significant relief to many ICS end users,
while still giving providers ample time
to adjust their systems and procedures.
259. As explained above, our goal is
to ensure a reasonable transition and
minimize disruption, while providing
relief to end users as quickly as
possible. We have the benefit of
understanding how the transition to
implement the interim interstate rate
caps occurred. Evidence in the record
about actual transition periods calls into
question protestations in the record
about the excessive time it will take to
renegotiate contracts, particularly for
prisons. We adopt here a 90-day
transition from publication in the
Federal Register for prisons and six
months from publication in the Federal
Register for jails for the adopted rate
caps. We find that this length of time
adequately balances the pressing need
for reform, affords ICS providers enough
time to prepare for the new rates, and
is amply supported by the record.
260. Evidence in the record indicates
that some ICS providers and their
customers have been acting to modify
contracts in an attempt to lock in
attractive terms at the expense of the
ratepayers, the end users, in
anticipation of this Order. We are
concerned that such activity may also
occur in between the adoption and
effective dates of this Order. We will be
vigilant in monitoring the industry
during the transition period. If we
observe or are made aware of evidence
of price gouging or other harmful
behavior through, but not limited to,
increased rates, ancillary service
charges, and/or site commissions, we
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:49 Dec 17, 2015
Jkt 238001
79171
will not hesitate to take appropriate
remedial action up to and including
enforcement action pursuant to our legal
authority under sections 201 and 276 or
referral to another appropriate agency.
J. Anti-Gaming Provisions
261. We are concerned that parties
may seek to negotiate agreements aimed
at circumventing the rules we adopt in
this Order, and we are particularly
concerned that parties will have an
incentive to do so before our new rules
take effect. To minimize this type of
‘‘gaming,’’ we prohibit ICS providers
from entering into new contracts
(including contract renewals)—or
negotiating amendments to existing
contracts—that would require or permit
providers to charge rates in excess of
our adopted rate caps, impose ancillary
service charges that are prohibited by
this Order, or charge ancillary service
charges that exceed the caps adopted in
this Order. These prohibitions will take
effect immediately upon publication of
the Order in the Federal Register.
262. We find that there is good cause
to make this requirement effective upon
publication. There is evidence in the
record that this type of gaming has
already occurred in anticipation of the
changes we enact in this Order. For
example, a recent Securus contract
requires the payment of a $4 million
minimum annual guarantee (MAG),
which advocates have called a ‘‘signing
bonus,’’ and subsequent MAG payments
equal to the greater of $3.5 million or 81
percent of commissionable revenues per
year. In determining whether good
cause exists, an agency should ‘‘balance
the necessity for immediate
implementation against principles of
fundamental fairness which require that
all affected persons be afforded a
reasonable amount of time to prepare for
the effective date of its ruling.’’ In this
case, the rule must take effect as soon
as possible in order to minimize gaming
of the sort already noted in the record,
and the attendant harm to prisoners and
their families in the form of unjust,
unreasonable, and unfair rates and fees.
In these circumstances, we find that the
need for immediate implementation
outweighs any concerns that parties
may not be afforded sufficient time to
prepare for the effective date of this
prohibition, particularly given that
parties have long been on notice that the
Commission might impose new
regulations governing ICS rates and
ancillary fees. We are not requiring
providers to take any action; instead we
are merely requiring that they refrain
from taking certain steps that would
effectively undermine our regulations
governing rates and ancillary service
charges. Accordingly, providers do not
need time to prepare to meet this
prohibition. Therefore, on balance, we
find good cause to make this
requirement effective upon publication
in the Federal Register.
K. Annual Reporting and Certification
Requirement
263. In the 2013 Order, the
Commission adopted an Annual
Reporting and Certification Requirement
that included the submission of
interstate and intrastate ICS rate and
demand data, as an additional means of
ensuring that each and every ICS
provider’s rates and practices were just,
reasonable, and fair, and remain in
compliance with the 2013 Order, as well
as to facilitate any future enforcement
that may be needed regarding the
adopted rules. Additionally, the
Commission adopted a requirement that
an officer or director from each ICS
provider file an annual certification
with the Commission as to the accuracy
of the data filed and as to the provider’s
compliance with all portions of the
adopted Order. These requirements
were later stayed by court order.
264. Recordkeeping and Reporting.
The Joint Provider Proposal suggests
that ICS providers ‘‘should be required
to provide certain information to the
Commission annually for three (3) years
to ensure the caps on per-minute rates
and any admin-support payments are
implemented as required.’’ Specifically,
the Proposal suggests that such
information should include four things:
‘‘a list of the ICS provider’s current
interstate and intrastate per-minute ICS
rates, the ICS provider’s current fee
amounts, the locations where the ICS
provider makes admin-support
payments, and the amount of those
admin-support payments.’’ The
Commission sought comment on this
proposal in the Second FNPRM.
265. In its comments, CPC
recommends that the Commission look
to the ‘‘Alabama model,’’ including the
‘‘specific reporting requirements that
will serve to monitor compliance with
those [adopted] restrictions.’’ In its 2014
Further Order Adopting Revised Inmate
Phone Service Rules Order, the Alabama
PSC adopted a number of recordkeeping
and reporting requirements. Items to be
recorded and reported annually include,
but are not limited, to, monthly number
of local, intrastate, and interstate calls;
monthly local, intrastate, and interstate
minutes of use; monthly local,
intrastate, and interstate call revenue,
divided into collect, prepaid collect,
prepaid debit, prepaid inmate calling
card, and direct-billed service, divided
by facility; ancillary call charges;
PO 00000
Frm 00037
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
E:\FR\FM\18DER2.SGM
18DER2
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES2
79172
Federal Register / Vol. 80, No. 243 / Friday, December 18, 2015 / Rules and Regulations
unused prepaid collect, prepaid debit,
and prepaid inmate phone card account
balances; and total number of calls
disconnected for suspected three-way
call violations. That order was
temporarily stayed by court order which
expired on July 1, 2015.
266. We find that a recordkeeping and
reporting requirement will best serve
the Commission’s stated goals of
ensuring that each and every ICS
provider’s rates and practices are just,
reasonable, and fair, and that they
remain in compliance with this Order.
We also believe that an annual
recordkeeping and reporting
requirement will help the Commission
capture any trends or changes in calling
patterns, will facilitate any future
enforcement action, and allow other
interested parties the ability to monitor
ICS providers’ compliance with the
Order. We also believe that such a
requirement is necessary because the
ICS industry is modernizing and will
continue to change. Consistent with the
Commission’s approach in the 2013
Order, if after an investigation it is
determined that ICS providers rates
and/or ancillary service charges are
unjust, unreasonable or unfair under
sections 201 and 276 of the Act, lower
rates will be prescribed and ICS
providers may be ordered to pay
refunds. Providers also may be found in
violation of our rules and face
additional forfeitures.
267. We thus require all ICS providers
to provide, on an annual basis,
categorized by facility and size of
facility, the following information: First,
we require all ICS providers to file their
current interstate, international and
intrastate ICS rates. Second, we require
all ICS providers to file their current
ancillary service charge amounts and
the instances of use of each. Third,
where an ICS provider makes site
commission payments, we require the
ICS provider to file the monthly amount
of such payment. Fourth, for ICS
providers that provided video visitation
services, either as a form of ICS or not,
during the reporting period, we require
that they file the minutes of use and perminute rates and ancillary service
charges for those services. Fifth, as
discussed in greater detail in the
Disability Access section above, we also
require that ICS providers report: (1)
The number of disability-related calls
they provided; (2) the number of
problems they experienced with such
calls, e.g., dropped calls, poor call
quality and the number of incidences of
each; and (3) the number of complaints
they received related to access to ICS by
TTY and TRS users.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:49 Dec 17, 2015
Jkt 238001
268. In order to facilitate compliance
with this requirement, we direct the
Wireline Competition Bureau to develop
a template for such annual reports and
provide for confidential treatment of
any particular information warranting it,
consistent with our rules. We believe
this will help ensure that the incoming
information is provided in the most
straight-forward and consistent manner.
The use of such a template will also be
beneficial to any interested parties that
want to view the information thus
encouraging increased public
participation in this proceeding. Each
annual report shall be submitted to the
Commission by April 1st of each year,
regarding the providers’ interstate,
international and intrastate ICS. The
first annual report will be due after the
Commission publishes Office of
Management and Budget (OMB)
approval pursuant to the Ordering
Clauses below. If for example, OMB
approval is granted in 2016 then the
first annual report and certification (as
discussed below) will be due on April
1, 2017 and cover the time period from
January 1, 2016 to December 31, 2016.
269. Cost-Benefit Analysis. We find
that a recordkeeping and reporting
requirement serves the Commission’s
goal of ensuring that ICS rates and
practices are just, reasonable, and fair,
and that they remain in compliance
with this Order. We find, on balance,
that the benefits of such recordkeeping
and reporting outweigh any potential
burden that may be imposed.
270. We find that such recordkeeping
and reporting requirements will help
monitor ICS providers’ compliance with
the Order, capture any trends or changes
in calling patterns, and will facilitate
any future enforcement action. Such a
requirement is necessary because the
ICS industry is modernizing and will
continue to change.
271. We find very few objections
raised to the reporting requirements,
and none to be persuasive. Additionally,
we also find no cost objections to these
requirements. We have taken steps to
minimize burdens on providers by
adopting less burdensome
recordkeeping requirements than some
of those suggested by commenters.
Moreover, any burdens associated with
providing limited reporting on these
calls are far outweighed by the benefits
such reporting will offer in terms of
greater transparency and heightened
accountability on the part of ICS
providers. Additionally, these data will
guide the Commission as it evaluates
next steps in the Further Notice.
272. Annual Certification. The
participants in the Joint Provider
Proposal suggest that all ICS providers
PO 00000
Frm 00038
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
should be required, in addition to their
recordkeeping and reporting
requirements, to submit an annual
certification signed by the company
Chief Executive Officer, Chief Financial
Officer, and General Counsel, under
penalty of perjury, certifying that the
company is in compliance with the
Commission’s ICS rate rules and
adopted payment rules. CenturyLink
counters that ‘‘there is no need for more
than a single officer to certify that the
company has complied with
Commission rules.’’
273. We agree with CenturyLink that
‘‘there is no need for more than a single
officer to certify that the company has
complied with Commission rules.’’ We
find that, on balance, requiring more
than one officer of an ICS provider to
certify to compliance would be
unnecessarily burdensome on some
providers and is in fact, contrary to the
manner in which the Commission
conducts other annual certifications.
Therefore we adopt CenturyLink’s
proposal and require one officer of each
ICS provider to annually certify its
companies’ compliance with our
adopted rules. The annual certification
should be submitted at the same time as
the annual report.
L. Consumer Disclosure Requirements
274. Background. In the 2013 Order,
the Commission reminded providers of
their current and ongoing obligations to
‘‘comply with existing Commission
rules.’’ Specifically, the Commission
reminded providers of their obligations
pursuant to section 64.710 of our rules,
which requires providers of inmate
operator services to disclose to the
consumer the total cost of the call prior
to connecting it, including any
surcharges or premise-imposed fees that
may apply to the call as well as methods
by which to make complaints
concerning the charges or collection
practices. Additionally, ICS providers
that are non-dominant interexchange
carriers must make their current rates,
terms, and conditions available to the
public via their company Web sites.
Any violation of such responsibilities,
or failure to comply with existing rules,
may subject ICS providers to
enforcement action, including, among
other penalties, the imposition of
monetary forfeitures.
275. In the Second FNPRM, the
Commission sought comment on ‘‘how
to ensure that rates and fees are more
transparent to consumers’’ and
specifically on the requirement that ICS
providers notify their customers
regarding the ICS options available to
them and the cost of those options. ICS
providers that offer interstate toll
E:\FR\FM\18DER2.SGM
18DER2
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 80, No. 243 / Friday, December 18, 2015 / Rules and Regulations
service are already required to post their
rates on their Web sites, and, to the
extent they offer inmate operator
services, their live agents are already
required to make certain notifications to
customers. The Commission sought
comment on whether providers’ Web
sites, automated IVRs, and live agents
should be required to offer in a more
prominent fashion no-cost or lower-cost
options before offering other, higherpriced optional services. The
Commission also sought comment on
two reform proposals that offered
suggestions for requiring the publication
of ancillary service charges.
276. The Joint Provider Proposal,
acknowledging existing requirements
for providers to publish interstate rates,
terms and conditions on their Web sites,
offered a detailed proposal regarding
notification requirements for so-called
‘‘convenience or premium payment
options,’’ and suggested that all
providers be required to ‘‘clearly and
conspicuously identify the required
information . . . so that it is actually
noticed and understood by the
customer.’’ Specifically, the Joint
Provider Proposal suggests that an ICS
provider ‘‘may provide this information
to consumers (1) on its Web site, (2) in
its web-posted rates, terms, and
conditions, (3) orally when provided in
a slow and deliberate manner and in a
reasonably understandable volume, or
(4) in other printed materials provided
to a customer.’’ The providers that
signed on to the Joint Provider Proposal
suggest that ‘‘clear and conspicuous’’
means that ‘‘notice would be apparent
to the reasonable customer,’’ and that to
determine the effectiveness of the
disclosure, the Commission should
‘‘consider the prominence of the
disclosure in comparison to other
information, the proximity and
placement of the information, the
absence of distracting elements, and the
clarity and understandability of the text
of the disclosure.’’ Pay Tel suggests that
on a Web site, postings must list call
rates and fees, as well as refund
instructions. Pay Tel also suggests that
the vendor Web site must provide a link
to the FCC Enforcement Bureau Web
site and the applicable state regulatory
agency Web site. Pay Tel also suggests
making facility-specific printed material
available at each facility. The
Commission explicitly sought comment
on these proposals in the Second
FNPRM.
277. In comments to the Second
FNPRM, CenturyLink notes that
especially in jails and short-term
facilities, payment decisions are
‘‘typically made in ‘real-time,’ as the
call is received from the inmate’’ and
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:49 Dec 17, 2015
Jkt 238001
that ‘‘there is no reasonable way for
called parties to make informed
decisions unless the ICS provider
proactively informs them of options in
clear, concise language prior to
payment.’’ CenturyLink further asserts
that ‘‘simple posting[s] on Web sites or
reactive responses upon request are not
sufficient’’ when faced with timesensitive situations such as initial
incarceration. The record indicates that
many consumers face the problem of
uncertainty with respect to the cost of
ICS. Praeses argues that in addition to
disclosing their ancillary service charges
in a prominent location on their Web
sites, providers should be required to
disclose all applicable fees at the time
that a consumer seeks a service that is
subject to an ancillary service charge
from a provider, but prior to the inmate
or call recipient incurring the fee. DC
Prisoners’ Project of the Washington
Lawyers’ Committee suggests that the
Commission require all ICS providers to
train their staff to disclose all rate and
fee information to anyone who contacts
the provider. In addition to the
suggestions in the Joint Provider
Proposal, GTL asserts that the
Commission ‘‘should enforce its existing
requirements regarding oral disclosures
and the posting of rates, terms, and
conditions.’’ GTL notes that ‘‘ICS
providers have ‘ongoing responsibilities’
to comply with these existing rules, and
violations of those responsibilities or
failure to comply with those existing
rules could subject ICS providers to
enforcement action.’’
278. Discussion. We believe that
transparency in rates, terms, and fees
will facilitate compliance with the
reforms and ensure that consumers are
informed of their choices. We find
persuasive arguments that ICS payment
decisions are often made in ‘‘real time,’’
especially in short-term detention
facilities, and ‘‘there is no reasonable
way for called parties to make informed
decisions’’ unless rates and terms are
clearly available for consumers prior to
the commencement of the call. For
example, transparency about the rates
charged for ICS will provide substantial
consumer protection benefits by
empowering consumers to make
informed decisions about the ICS
offerings they decide to use. We also
applaud voluntary commitments that
enhance transparency for consumers.
Here, we supplement our existing rules
to require ICS providers to clearly and
accurately disclose their interstate,
international and intrastate rates and
ancillary service charges to consumers.
The new rule we adopt will provide key
consumer benefits with minimal burden
PO 00000
Frm 00039
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
79173
on ICS providers. Ensuring that end
users know the costs of the services they
seek to use will help consumers make
informed decisions about what types of
services they can afford and for what
amount of time.
279. We do not mandate a specific
format for how consumer disclosures
must be made. Rather, we find that
suggestions for disclosure such as those
in the Joint Provider Proposal offer a
reasonable framework as to how to make
these disclosures. However, we note
that this would not necessarily be the
only framework for compliance. We will
formally evaluate the reasonableness of
the Joint Provider Proposal and any
other disclosure formats if and when
complaints arise as to the adequacy of
the disclosures. We note that each
failure to disclose all charges to
consumers is counted as an individual
violation, which should create a
significant incentive for compliance. In
addition, the Commission shall evaluate
disclosures of all consumer charges for
reasonableness, in part, on the basis of
the following factors:
• Disclosure of information regarding
all material charges, such as the
applicable rate, any and all ancillary
service charges—whether one time or
recurring—including those to initiate
service, and the name, definition and
cost of each rate or fee;
• Use of plain language accessible to
current and prospective end users;
• Description of single call and
related services and disclosures making
clear that consumers have less-costly
options rather than single call and
related services;
• Ability of end users to easily
understand the disclosure;
• Timeliness of any updates/changes
to the rates and fees, prior to any
updates/changes;
• Availability of the disclosure in a
prominent location on the ICS
provider’s Web site;
• Listing of the name, address, and
toll-free number of the ICS provider;
and
• Listing of the toll-free number for
the FCC Consumer Help Center (888–
225–5322).
280. Providers should already be
informing customers about the total
amount on a per-call basis that they will
be charged so the disclosure
requirements should not be onerous or
a significant new burden. Indeed, the
addition to our rules with respect to
ancillary service charges should in fact
simplify transparency, as it greatly
reduces the number and variable rates of
allowable ancillary service charges, and
thus charges ICS providers must
disclose to consumers. This information
E:\FR\FM\18DER2.SGM
18DER2
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES2
79174
Federal Register / Vol. 80, No. 243 / Friday, December 18, 2015 / Rules and Regulations
is relevant to consumer decision
making, and the providers must also
keep this information in order to
comply with the Annual Reporting and
Certification Requirements adopted
herein.
281. The new disclosure rule
discussed above falls well within the
confines of the First Amendment. As
explained, these disclosures serve
important government purposes,
ensuring that end users have accurate
and accessible information about ICS
providers’ services. This information is
central both to preventing consumer
deception and to the overall deployment
and operation of ICS.
282. The Supreme Court has made
plain in Zauderer v. Office of
Disciplinary Counsel of Supreme Court
of Ohio that the government has broad
discretion in requiring the disclosure of
information to prevent consumer
deception and ensure complete
information in the marketplace. Under
Zauderer, mandatory factual disclosures
will be sustained ‘‘as long as disclosure
requirements are reasonably related to
the State’s interest in preventing
deception to consumers.’’ As the Court
observed, ‘‘the First Amendment
interests implicated by disclosure
requirements are substantially weaker
than those at stake when speech is
actually suppressed.’’ The DC Circuit
recently reaffirmed these principles in
American Meat Institute v. United
States Department of Agriculture, an en
banc decision in which the Court joined
the First and Second Circuit Courts of
Appeals in recognizing that other
government interests beyond preventing
consumer deception may be invoked to
sustain a disclosure mandate under
Zauderer.
283. The new disclosure rule and
disclosure language suggested in this
Order clearly pass muster under these
precedents. Preventing consumer
deception in the ICS market lies at the
heart of the disclosure rule we adopt
today. The Commission has found that
ICS providers have the incentive and
ability to engage in harmful practices, as
discussed above. Similarly, the
suggested disclosure language is
designed to prevent confusion to all
consumers of the ICS providers’
services, and serve to curb providers’
incentives to engage in harmful
practices by shedding light on the
business practices of ICS providers.
Accurate information about ICS
provider offerings encourages consumer
choice and the widespread deployment
of ICS. In sum, the government interests
supporting the disclosure rule (as well
as the suggested disclosure language), in
addition to the interest of preventing
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:49 Dec 17, 2015
Jkt 238001
consumer deception, are substantial and
justify our consumer disclosure
suggestions.
284. In addition, the disclosure rule
adopted in this Order meets the analysis
the Supreme Court developed for
commercial speech cases in Central
Hudson Gas & Elec. Corp. v. Public
Serv. Comm’n. Central Hudson’s test
first asks whether the expression is
protected by the First Amendment,
which requires that the speech concern
lawful activity and not be misleading.
Next, the Court asks whether the
asserted governmental interest is
substantial. If the first two prongs of the
analysis are met, the Court then
determines whether the regulation
directly advances the governmental
interest asserted and whether it is not
more extensive than necessary to serve
that interest. Requiring ICS providers to
disclose information about ICS rates
meets this four-part test. First, ICS
providers’ rate information qualifies as
an expression protected by the First
Amendment, as it is speech concerning
lawful activity that is not misleading.
Second, as explained elsewhere in this
Order, the Commission has a substantial
interest in consumer protection and
advancing the public interest,
particularly where, as here, Congress
has directed the Commission to ensure
that ICS rates are just, reasonable and
fair, pursuant to regulations that
redound ‘‘to the benefit of the general
public.’’ Third, as explained above, the
regulation directly advances the public
interest and consumer protection in
requiring disclosure of this information,
as transparency in rates and charges
allows consumers to make more
informed choices. Finally, this new
consumer disclosure requirement is not
more extensive than is necessary to
protect consumers. Since ICS providers
have already been operating under
similar requirements, this information is
readily available to them and, as
explained above, we do not prescribe a
particular format for how consumer
disclosures must be made, thereby
affording providers leeway to comply
with the revised rule in a flexible,
individualized manner that minimizes
burden.
285. Cost-Benefit Analysis. We find
that, on balance, requiring ICS providers
to disclose information for their
intrastate, interstate and international
ICS rates, categorized by facility and
size of facility, as well as ancillary
service charges, is not overly
burdensome. These requirements are
necessary to ensuring that end users
know the costs of the services they seek
to use and helps consumers make
informed decisions about what types of
PO 00000
Frm 00040
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
services they can afford and for what
amount of time.
286. The Commission has found that
ICS providers have the incentive and
ability to engage in harmful practices, as
discussed above. Commenters have
asked the Commission to mandate
additional disclosure and transparency
regarding ICS rates and fees. Similarly,
these disclosure requirements are
designed to prevent confusion to all
consumers of the ICS providers’
services, and serve to curb providers’
incentives by shedding light on the
business practices of ICS providers.
Numerous commenters support these
reforms.
287. These requirements provide key
consumer benefits with minimal burden
on ICS providers. Providers currently
are required to post their rates publicly
on their Web sites. Additionally,
providers must keep this information to
comply with the Mandatory Data
Collection and Annual Reporting and
Certification Requirements adopted
herein.
288. To minimize any potential
burden on providers, the Commission
does not prescribe a particular format
for how consumer disclosures must be
made, but suggests a framework for
consideration and allows providers
flexibility in adopting such disclosures,
thus allowing providers with maximum
flexibility and minimum burden.
M. Severability
289. All of the rules that are adopted
in this Order are designed to ensure just,
reasonable, and fair ICS rates. Each of
the reforms we undertake in this Order
serve a particular function toward this
goal. Therefore, it is our intent that each
of the rules and regulations adopted
herein shall be severable. We believe
that ICS end users will benefit from the
rates caps adopted and will also benefit
separately from the adopted ancillary
service charge caps. If any of the rules
or regulations, or portions thereof
including, for example, any portion of
our rate caps and ancillary service
charge rules, are declared invalid or
unenforceable for any reason, it is our
intent that the remaining rules shall be
in full force and effect.
N. Outstanding Petitions
290. After the Commission released
the 2013 Order, numerous entities
petitioned the Commission for a stay of
the new rules and requirements. The
requests for stay generally expressed
concern about one or more of the
following categories of issues: (1) That
a ‘‘one-size-fits-all’’ approach for ICS
rate reform will be ineffective, and
ignores the fact that jails incur real costs
E:\FR\FM\18DER2.SGM
18DER2
Federal Register / Vol. 80, No. 243 / Friday, December 18, 2015 / Rules and Regulations
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES2
and will face budget shortfalls under the
Commission’s adopted approach; (2) the
continued need for site commissions, or
a concern about how to manage
correctional budgets built on a reliance
on those site commissions; (3) a concern
about the Commission seeking comment
on asserting jurisdiction over intrastate
ICS calls or classifying all ICS calls as
interstate; (4) a potentially harmful
impact on the security at facilities and
the safety of citizens stemming from the
Commission’s rules and requirements;
and (5) general requests that the
Commission stay its Order with no legal
analysis or justifications for the request.
We dismiss the first four categories on
the basis that the present order
adequately addresses and answers the
arguments and concerns contained
within them. We adopt tiered rate caps
based on population size, address site
commissions and security concerns, as
well as assert jurisdiction over intrastate
ICS, in this Order. We dismiss the fifth
category of stay requests on the basis
that they do not present any legal
reasoning or analysis to justify a stay of
our rules and have been rendered moot
by this Order.
O. Ex Parte Requirements
291. This proceeding shall be treated
as a ‘‘permit-but-disclose’’ proceeding in
accordance with the Commission’s ex
parte rules. Persons making ex parte
presentations must file a copy of any
written presentation or a memorandum
summarizing any oral presentation
within two business days after the
presentation (unless a different deadline
applicable to the Sunshine period
applies). Persons making oral ex parte
presentations are reminded that
memoranda summarizing the
presentation must (1) list all persons
attending or otherwise participating in
the meeting at which the ex parte
presentation was made, and (2)
summarize all data presented and
arguments made during the
presentation. Memoranda must contain
a summary of the substance of the ex
parte presentation ad not merely a list
of the subjects discussed. More than a
one or two sentence description of the
views and arguments presented is
generally required. If the oral
presentation consisted in whole or in
part of the presentation of data or
arguments already reflected in the
presenter’s written comments,
memoranda or other filings in the
proceeding, the presenter may provide
citations to such data or arguments in
his or her prior comments, memoranda,
or other filings (specifying the relevant
page and/or paragraph numbers where
such data or arguments can be found) in
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:49 Dec 17, 2015
Jkt 238001
lieu of summarizing them in the
memorandum. Documents shown or
given to Commission staff during ex
parte meetings are deemed to be written
ex parte presentations and must be filed
consistent with rule 1.1206(b). In
proceedings governed by rule 1.49(f) or
for which the Commission has made
available a method of electronic filing,
written ex parte presentations and
memoranda summarizing oral ex parte
presentations, and all attachments
thereto, must be filed through the
electronic comment filing system
available for that proceeding, and must
be filed in their native format (e.g., .doc,
.xml, .ppt, searchable .pdf). Participants
in this proceeding should familiarize
themselves with the Commission’s ex
parte rules.
P. Paperwork Reduction Act Analysis
292. This Report and Order contains
new or modified information collection
requirements subject to the Paperwork
Reduction Act of 1995 (PRA), Public
Law 104–13. It will be submitted to the
Office of Management and Budget
(OMB) for review under section 3507(d)
of the PRA. OMB, the general public,
and other Federal agencies are invited to
comment on the new or modified
information collection requirements
contained in the proceeding. In
addition, we note that pursuant to the
Small Business Paperwork Relief Act of
2002, Public Law 107–198, see 44 U.S.C.
3506(4), we previously sought comment
on how the Commission might further
reduce the information collection
burden for small business concerns with
fewer than 25 employees.
Q. Congressional Review Act
293. The Commission will send a
copy of this Report and Order in a
report to be sent to Congress and the
Government Accountability Office
pursuant to the Congressional Review
Act. See 5 U.S.C. 801(a)(1)(A).
R. Final Regulatory Flexibility Analysis
1. As required by the Regulatory
Flexibility Act of 1980, as amended
(RFA). an Initial Regulatory Flexibility
Analysis (IRFA) was incorporated in the
Second Notice of Proposed Rulemaking
(Second FNPRM) in WC Docket 12–375.
The Commission sought written public
comment on the proposals in the
Second FNPRM, including comment on
the IRFA. The Commission did not
receive comments directed toward the
IRFA. This Final Regulatory Flexibility
Analysis (FRFA) conforms to the RFA.
PO 00000
Frm 00041
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
79175
1. Need for, and Objectives of, the
Report and Order
294. The Second Report and Order
(Order) adopted rules to ensure that
interstate, intrastate, and international
inmate calling service (ICS) rates in
correctional institutions are just,
reasonable, and fair. In the initiating
Second FNPRM, the Commission sought
information on issues related to the ICS
market, payments to correctional
facilities, ICS interstate and intrastate
rates, ancillary fees, additional ways to
promote competition, harmonization of
state regulations, existing contracts,
transition periods, accessible ICS,
advanced ICS, periodic review,
enforcement, and a cost/benefit analysis
of reform proposals.
295. In this Order, the Commission
adopts comprehensive reform of all
aspects of ICS to correct a market
failure, foster market efficiencies,
encourage ongoing state reforms and
ensure that ICS rates and charges
comply with the Communications Act.
The Order does this by addressing
interstate and intrastate ICS rates,
payments to correctional facilities,
ancillary service charges, connection
and per-call charges, flat-rate charges,
harmonization with state regulations,
disability access, transition periods,
periodic review, mandatory data
collection, waivers, and consumer
protection measures such as annual
certification and reporting requirements.
The reforms adopted in this Order apply
to ICS offered in all correctional facility
types and regardless of technology used
to deliver the services.
2. Summary of Significant Issues Raised
by Public Comments in Response to the
IRFA
296. The Commission did not receive
comments specifically addressing the
rules and policies proposed in the IRFA.
3. Description and Estimate of the
Number of Small Entities to Which
Rules Will Apply
297. Small Businesses. Nationwide,
there are a total of approximately 27.9
million small businesses, according to
the SBA.
298. Wired Telecommunications
Carriers. The SBA has developed a
small business size standard for Wired
Telecommunications Carriers, which
consists of all such companies having
1,500 or fewer employees. According to
Census Bureau data for 2007, there were
3,188 firms in this category, total, that
operated for the entire year. Of this
total, 3,144 firms had employment of
999 or fewer employees, and 44 firms
had employment of 1,000 employees or
E:\FR\FM\18DER2.SGM
18DER2
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES2
79176
Federal Register / Vol. 80, No. 243 / Friday, December 18, 2015 / Rules and Regulations
more. Thus, under this size standard,
the majority of firms can be considered
small.
299. Local Exchange Carriers (LECs).
Neither the Commission nor the SBA
has developed a size standard for small
businesses specifically applicable to
local exchange services. The closest
applicable size standard under SBA
rules is for Wired Telecommunications
Carriers. Under that size standard, such
a business is small if it has 1,500 or
fewer employees. According to
Commission data, 1,307 carriers
reported that they were incumbent local
exchange service providers. Of these
1,307 carriers, an estimated 1,006 have
1,500 or fewer employees and 301 have
more than 1,500 employees.
Consequently, the Commission
estimates that most providers of local
exchange service are small entities that
may be affected by the Commission’s
action.
300. Incumbent Local Exchange
Carriers (incumbent LECs). Neither the
Commission nor the SBA has developed
a size standard for small businesses
specifically applicable to incumbent
local exchange services. The closest
applicable size standard under SBA
rules is for Wired Telecommunications
Carriers. Under that size standard, such
a business is small if it has 1,500 or
fewer employees. According to
Commission data, 1,307 carriers
reported that they were incumbent local
exchange service providers. Of these
1,307 carriers, an estimated 1,006 have
1,500 or fewer employees and 301 have
more than 1,500 employees.
Consequently, the Commission
estimates that most providers of
incumbent local exchange service are
small businesses that may be affected by
the Commission’s action.
301. The Commission has included
small incumbent LECs in this present
RFA analysis. As noted above, a ‘‘small
business’’ under the RFA is one that,
inter alia, meets the pertinent small
business size standard (e.g., a telephone
communications business having 1,500
or fewer employees), and ‘‘is not
dominant in its field of operation.’’ The
SBA’s Office of Advocacy contends that,
for RFA purposes, small incumbent
LECs are not dominant in their field of
operation because any such dominance
is not ‘‘national’’ in scope. The
Commission has therefore included
small incumbent LECs in this RFA
analysis, although it emphasizes that
this RFA action has no effect on
Commission analyses and
determinations in other, non-RFA
contexts.
302. Competitive Local Exchange
Carriers (Competitive LECs),
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:49 Dec 17, 2015
Jkt 238001
Competitive Access Providers (CAPs),
Shared-Tenant Service Providers, and
Other Local Service Providers. Neither
the Commission nor the SBA has
developed a small business size
standard specifically for these service
providers. The appropriate size standard
under SBA rules is for the category
Wired Telecommunications Carriers.
Under that size standard, such a
business is small if it has 1,500 or fewer
employees. According to Commission
data, 1,442 carriers reported that they
were engaged in the provision of either
competitive local exchange services or
competitive access provider services. Of
these 1,442 carriers, an estimated 1,256
have 1,500 or fewer employees and 186
have more than 1,500 employees. In
addition, 17 carriers have reported that
they are Shared-Tenant Service
Providers, and all 17 are estimated to
have 1,500 or fewer employees. In
addition, 72 carriers have reported that
they are Other Local Service Providers.
Of the 72, 70 have 1,500 or fewer
employees and two have more than
1,500 employees. Consequently, the
Commission estimates that most
providers of competitive local exchange
service, competitive access providers,
Shared-Tenant Service Providers, and
Other Local Service Providers are small
entities that may be affected by the
Commission’s action.
303. Interexchange Carriers (IXCs).
Neither the Commission nor the SBA
has developed a size standard for small
businesses specifically applicable to
interexchange services. The closest
applicable size standard under SBA
rules is for Wired Telecommunications
Carriers. Under that size standard, such
a business is small if it has 1,500 or
fewer employees. According to
Commission data, 359 companies
reported that their primary
telecommunications service activity was
the provision of interexchange services.
Of these 359 companies, an estimated
317 have 1,500 or fewer employees and
42 have more than 1,500 employees.
Consequently, the Commission
estimates that the majority of
interexchange service providers are
small entities that may be affected by
the Commission’s action.
304. Local Resellers. The SBA has
developed a small business size
standard for the category of
Telecommunications Resellers. Under
that size standard, such a business is
small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees.
According to Commission data, 213
carriers have reported that they are
engaged in the provision of local resale
services. Of these, an estimated 211
have 1,500 or fewer employees and two
have more than 1,500 employees.
PO 00000
Frm 00042
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
Consequently, the Commission
estimates that the majority of local
resellers are small entities that may be
affected by the Commission’s action.
305. Toll Resellers. The SBA has
developed a small business size
standard for the category of
Telecommunications Resellers. Under
that size standard, such a business is
small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees.
According to Commission data, 881
carriers have reported that they are
engaged in the provision of toll resale
services. Of these, an estimated 857
have 1,500 or fewer employees and 24
have more than 1,500 employees.
Consequently, the Commission
estimates that the majority of toll
resellers are small entities that may be
affected by the Commission’s action.
306. Other Toll Carriers. Neither the
Commission nor the SBA has developed
a size standard for small businesses
specifically applicable to Other Toll
Carriers. This category includes toll
carriers that do not fall within the
categories of interexchange carriers,
operator service providers, prepaid
calling card providers, satellite service
carriers, or toll resellers. The closest
applicable size standard under SBA
rules is for Wired Telecommunications
Carriers. Under that size standard, such
a business is small if it has 1,500 or
fewer employees. According to
Commission data, 284 companies
reported that their primary
telecommunications service activity was
the provision of other toll carriage. Of
these, an estimated 279 have 1,500 or
fewer employees and five have more
than 1,500 employees. Consequently,
the Commission estimates that most
Other Toll Carriers are small entities
that may be affected by the
Commission’s action.
307. Payphone Service Providers
(PSPs). Neither the Commission nor the
SBA has developed a small business
size standard specifically for payphone
services providers. The appropriate size
standard under SBA rules is for the
category Wired Telecommunications
Carriers. Under that size standard, such
a business is small if it has 1,500 or
fewer employees. According to
Commission data, 535 carriers have
reported that they are engaged in the
provision of payphone services. Of
these, an estimated 531 have 1,500 or
fewer employees and four have more
than 1,500 employees. Consequently,
the Commission estimates that the
majority of payphone service providers
are small entities that may be affected
by the Commission’s action.
E:\FR\FM\18DER2.SGM
18DER2
Federal Register / Vol. 80, No. 243 / Friday, December 18, 2015 / Rules and Regulations
4. Description of Projected Reporting,
Recordkeeping, and Other Compliance
Requirements for Small Entities
308. Recordkeeping, Reporting, and
Certification. The Order requires that all
ICS providers file annually data,
categorized by facility and size of
facility, on their current intrastate,
interstate, and international ICS rates.
The Commission also requires ICS
providers to file their current ancillary
service charge amounts and the
instances of use of each. ICS providers
that make site commission payments
must file the monthly amount of any
such payment. The Commission
requires ICS providers that provided
video visitation services, either as a
form of ICS or not, during the reporting
period, to file the minutes of use and
per-minute rates for those services. As
discussed in greater detail in the
Disability Access section above, the
Commission also requires that ICS
providers report: (1) The number of
disability-related calls they provided;
(2) the number of problems they
experienced with such calls; and (3) the
number of complaints they received
related to access to ICS by TTY and TRS
users e.g., dropped calls, poor call
quality and the number of incidences of
each. The adopted reporting
requirements will facilitate enforcement
and act as an additional means of
ensuring that ICS providers’ rates and
practices are just, reasonable, fair and in
compliance with the Order.
309. The Commission delegates to the
Wireline Competition Bureau (Bureau)
the authority to adopt a template for
submitting the required data,
information, and certifications.
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES2
5. Steps Taken To Minimize the
Significant Economic Impact on Small
Entities, and Significant Alternatives
Considered
310. The RFA requires an agency to
describe any significant, specifically
small business, alternatives that it has
considered in reaching its proposed
approach, which may include the
following four alternatives (among
others): ‘‘(1) the establishment of
differing compliance or reporting
requirements or timetables that take into
account the resources available to small
entities; (2) the clarification,
consolidation, or simplification of
compliance and reporting requirements
under the rules for such small entities;
(3) the use of performance rather than
design standards; and (4) an exemption
from coverage of the rule, or any part
thereof, for such small entities.’’
311. The Commission needs access to
data that are comprehensive, reliable,
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:49 Dec 17, 2015
Jkt 238001
sufficiently disaggregated, and reported
in a standardized manner. The Order
recognizes, however, that reporting
obligations impose burdens on the
reporting providers. Consequently, the
Commission limits its collection to
information that is narrowly tailored to
meet its needs.
312. Monitoring and Certification. The
Commission requires ICS providers to
submit annually their data on their
intrastate, interstate and international
ICS rates, categorized by facility and
size of facility. The Commission
requires ICS providers to file their
charges to consumers that are ancillary
to providing the telecommunications
piece of ICS. Providers are currently
required to post their rates publicly on
their Web sites. Thus, this additional
filing requirement should entail
minimal additional compliance burden,
even for the largest ICS providers.
313. The information on providers’
Web sites is not certified and is
generally not available in a format that
will provide the per-call details that the
Commission requires to meet its
statutory obligations. Thus, the
Commission further requires each
provider to annually certify its
compliance with other portions of the
Order. The Commission finds that
without a uniform, comprehensive
dataset with which to evaluate ICS
providers’ rates, the Commission’s
analyses will be incomplete. The
Commission recognizes that any
information collection imposes burdens,
which may be most keenly felt by
smaller providers, but concludes that
the benefits of having comprehensive
data substantially outweigh the burdens.
Additionally, some of these potential
burdens, such as the filing of rates
currently required to be posted on an
ICS provider’s Web site, are minimally
burdensome.
314. Data Collection. The Commission
is cognizant of the burdens of data
collections, and has therefore taken
steps to minimize burdens, including
directing the Bureau to adopt a template
for filing the data that minimizes
burdens on providers by maximizing
uniformity and ease of filing, while still
allowing the Commission to gather the
necessary data. The Commission also
finds that without a uniform,
comprehensive dataset with which to
evaluate ICS providers’ costs, its
analyses will be incomplete, and its
ability to establish ICS rate caps will be
severely impaired. The Commission
thus concludes that requiring ICS
providers to report this cost data
appropriately balances any burdens of
reporting with the Commission’s need
PO 00000
Frm 00043
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
79177
for the data required to carry out its
statutory duties.
6. Report to Congress
315. The Commission will send a
copy of the Order, including this FRFA,
in a report to be sent to Congress
pursuant to the Small Business
Regulatory Enforcement Fairness Act of
1996. In addition, the Commission will
send a copy of the Order, including this
FRFA, to the Chief Counsel for
Advocacy of the Small Business
Administration. A copy of the Order
and FRFA (or summaries thereof) will
also be published in the Federal
Register.
V. Ordering Clauses
316. Accordingly, it is ordered that,
pursuant to sections 1, 2, 4(i)–(j), 201(b),
215, 218, 220, 276, 303(r), and 403 of
the Communications Act of 1934, as
amended, 47 U.S.C. 151, 152, 154(i)–(j),
201(b), 215, 218, 220, 276, 303(r), and
403 this Second Report and Order is
adopted.
317. It is further ordered that Part 64
of the Commission’s Rules, 47 CFR part
64, is amended as set forth in Appendix
A of the Second Report and Order.
These rules shall become effective
March 17, 2016.
318. It is further ordered, that the
prohibition against entering into new
contracts,—or negotiating amendments
to existing contracts, as discussed in
paragraphs 261 and 262, herein, shall
take effect immediately upon
publication in the Federal Register.
319. It is further ordered, that the
Commission’s Consumer and
Governmental Affairs Bureau, Reference
Information Center, shall send a copy of
this Second Report and Order, including
the Final Regulatory Flexibility
Analysis, to the Chief Counsel for
Advocacy of the Small Business
Administration.
320. It is further ordered, that
pursuant to sections 1.4(b)(1) and
1.103(a) of the Commission’s rules, 47
CFR 1.4(b)(1) and 1.103(a), that the
Compliance date for this Second Report
and Order shall be January 19, 2016.
List of Subjects in 47 CFR Part 64
Claims, Communications common
carriers, Computer technology, Credit,
Foreign relations, Individuals with
disabilities, Political candidates, Radio,
Reporting and recordkeeping
requirements, Telecommunications,
Telegraph, Telephone.
E:\FR\FM\18DER2.SGM
18DER2
79178
Federal Register / Vol. 80, No. 243 / Friday, December 18, 2015 / Rules and Regulations
Federal Communications Commission.
Gloria J. Miles,
Federal Register Liaison Officer, Office of the
Secretary.
Final Rules
For the reasons discussed in the
preamble, the Federal Communications
Commission amends 47 CFR part 64 as
follows:
PART 64—MISCELLANEOUS RULES
RELATING TO COMMON CARRIERS
1. The authority citation for part 64
continues to read as follows:
■
Authority: 47 U.S.C. 154, 254(k);
403(b)(2)(B), (c), Pub. L. 104–104, 110 Stat.
56. Interpret or apply 47 U.S.C. 201, 218, 222,
225, 226, 227, 228, 254(k), 616, 620, and the
Middle Class Tax Relief and Job Creation Act
of 2012, Pub. L. 112–96, unless otherwise
noted.
2. Section 64.6000 is revised to read
as follows:
■
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES2
§ 64.6000
Definitions.
As used in this subpart:
(a) Ancillary Service Charge means
any charge Consumers may be assess for
the use of Inmate Calling services that
are not included in the per-minute
charges assessed for individual calls.
Ancillary Service Charges that may be
charged include the following. All other
Ancillary Service Charges are
prohibited.
(1) Automated Payment Fees means
credit card payment, debit card
payment, and bill processing fees,
including fees for payments made by
interactive voice response (IVR), web, or
kiosk;
(2) Fees for Single-Call and Related
Services means billing arrangements
whereby an Inmate’s collect calls are
billed through a third party on a per-call
basis, where the called party does not
have an account with the Provider of
Inmate Calling Services or does not
want to establish an account;
(3) Live Agent Fee means a fee
associated with the optional use of a
live operator to complete Inmate Calling
Services transactions;
(4) Paper Bill/Statement Fees means
fees associated with providing
customers of Inmate Calling Services an
optional paper billing statement;
(5) Third-Party Financial Transaction
Fees means the exact fees, with no
markup, that Providers of Inmate
Calling Services are charged by third
parties to transfer money or process
financial transactions to facilitate a
Consumer’s ability to make account
payments via a third party.
(b) Authorized Fee means a
government authorized, but
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:49 Dec 17, 2015
Jkt 238001
discretionary, fee which a Provider must
remit to a federal, state, or local
government, and which a Provider is
permitted, but not required, to pass
through to Consumers. An Authorized
Fee may not include a markup, unless
the markup is specifically authorized by
a federal, state, or local statute, rule, or
regulation.
(c) Average Daily Population (ADP)
means the sum of all inmates in a
facility for each day of the preceding
calendar year, divided by the number of
days in the year. ADP shall be
calculated in accordance with
§ 64.6010(e) and (f);
(d) Collect Calling means an
arrangement whereby the called party
takes affirmative action clearly
indicating that it will pay the charges
associated with a call originating from
an Inmate Telephone;
(e) Consumer means the party paying
a Provider of Inmate Calling Services;
(f) Correctional Facility or
Correctional Institution means a Jail or
a Prison;
(g) Debit Calling means a
presubscription or comparable service
which allows an Inmate, or someone
acting on an Inmate’s behalf, to fund an
account set up though a Provider that
can be used to pay for Inmate Calling
Services calls originated by the Inmate;
(h) Flat Rate Calling means a calling
plan under which a Provider charges a
single fee for an Inmate Calling Services
call, regardless of the duration of the
call;
(i) Inmate means a person detained at
a Jail or Prison, regardless of the
duration of the detention;
(j) Inmate Calling Service means a
service that allows Inmates to make
calls to individuals outside the
Correctional Facility where the Inmate
is being held, regardless of the
technology used to deliver the service;
(k) Inmate Telephone means a
telephone instrument, or other device
capable of initiating calls, set aside by
authorities of a Correctional Facility for
use by Inmates;
(l) International Calls means calls that
originate in the United States and
terminate outside the United States;
(m) Jail means a facility of a local,
state, or federal law enforcement agency
that is used primarily to hold
individuals who are;
(1) Awaiting adjudication of criminal
charges;
(2) Post-conviction and committed to
confinement for sentences of one year or
less; or
(3) Post-conviction and awaiting
transfer to another facility. The term
also includes city, county or regional
facilities that have contracted with a
PO 00000
Frm 00044
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
private company to manage day-to-day
operations; privately-owned and
operated facilities primarily engaged in
housing city, county or regional
inmates; and facilities used to detain
individuals pursuant to a contract with
U.S. Immigration and Customs
Enforcement;
(n) Mandatory Tax or Mandatory Fee
means a fee that a Provider is required
to collect directly from Consumers, and
remit to federal, state, or local
governments;
(o) Per-Call, or Per-Connection Charge
means a one-time fee charged to a
Consumer at call initiation;
(p) Prepaid Calling means a
presubscription or comparable service
in which a Consumer, other than an
Inmate, funds an account set up through
a Provider of Inmate Calling Services.
Funds from the account can then be
used to pay for Inmate Calling Services,
including calls that originate with an
Inmate;
(q) Prepaid Collect Calling means a
calling arrangement that allows an
Inmate to initiate an Inmate Calling
Services call without having a preestablished billing arrangement and also
provides a means, within that call, for
the called party to establish an
arrangement to be billed directly by the
Provider of Inmate Calling Services for
future calls from the same Inmate;
(r) Prison means a facility operated by
a territorial, state, or federal agency that
is used primarily to confine individuals
convicted of felonies and sentenced to
terms in excess of one year. The term
also includes public and private
facilities that provide outsource housing
to other agencies such as the State
Departments of Correction and the
Federal Bureau of Prisons; and facilities
that would otherwise fall under the
definition of a Jail but in which the
majority of inmates are post-conviction
or are committed to confinement for
sentences of longer than one year;
(s) Provider of Inmate Calling
Services, or Provider means any
communications service provider that
provides Inmate Calling Services,
regardless of the technology used;
(t) Site Commission means any form
of monetary payment, in-kind payment,
gift, exchange of services or goods, fee,
technology allowance, or product that a
Provider of Inmate Calling Services or
affiliate of an Provider of Inmate Calling
Services may pay, give, donate, or
otherwise provide to an entity that
operates a correctional institution, an
entity with which the Provider of
Inmate Calling Services enters into an
agreement to provide ICS, a
governmental agency that oversees a
correctional facility, the city, county, or
E:\FR\FM\18DER2.SGM
18DER2
Federal Register / Vol. 80, No. 243 / Friday, December 18, 2015 / Rules and Regulations
Debit Calling, Prepaid Calling, or
Prepaid Collect Calling in excess of:
(1) $0.22 in Jails with an ADP of
0–349;
(2) $0.16 in Jails with an ADP of 350–
999; or
(3) $0.14 in Jails with an ADP of 1,000
or greater.
state where a facility is located, or an
agent of any such facility.
■ 3. Section 64.6010 is revised to read
as follows:
§ 64.6010
caps.
Inmate Calling Services rate
(a) No Provider shall charge, in the
Jails it serves, a per-minute rate for
Debit/prepaid
rate cap per
MOU
Size and type of facility
0–349 Jail ADP ................................................................................................
350–999 Jail ADP ............................................................................................
1,000+ Jail ADP ...............................................................................................
(d) No Provider shall charge, in the
Prisons it serves, a per-minute rate for
Collect Calling in excess of:
(1) $0.14 after March 17, 2016;
(2) $0.13 after July 1, 2017; and
(3) $0.11 after July 1, 2018, and going
forward.
(e) For purposes of this section, the
initial ADP shall be calculated, for all of
the Correctional Facilities covered by an
Inmate Calling Services contract, by
summing the total number of inmates
from January 1, 2015, through January
19, 2016, divided by the number of days
in that time period;
(f) In subsequent years, for all of the
correctional facilities covered by an
Inmate Calling Services contract, the
ADP will be the sum of the total number
of inmates from January 1st through
December 31st divided by the number of
days in the year and will become
effective on January 31st of the
following year.
■ 4. Section 64.6020 is revised to read
as follows:
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES2
§ 64.6020
Ancillary Service Charge.
(a) No Provider shall charge an
Ancillary Service Charge other than
those permitted charges listed in
§ 64.6000.
(b) No Provider shall charge a rate for
a permitted Ancillary Service Charge in
excess of:
(1) For Automated Payment Fees—
$3.00 per use;
(2) For Single-Call and Related
Services—the exact transaction fee
charged by the third-party provider,
with no markup, plus the adopted, perminute rate;
(3) For Live Agent Fee—$5.95 per use;
(4) For Paper Bill/Statement Fee—
$2.00 per use;
(5) For Third-Party Financial
Transaction Fees—the exact fees, with
no markup that result from the
transaction.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:49 Dec 17, 2015
Jkt 238001
5. Section 64.6030 is revised to read
as follows:
§ 64.6030
rate cap.
Inmate Calling Services interim
No Provider shall charge a rate for
Collect Calling in excess of $0.25 per
minute, or a rate for Debit Calling,
Prepaid Calling, or Prepaid Collect
Calling in excess of $0.21 per minute.
These interim rate caps shall sunset
upon the effectiveness of the rates
established in § 64.6010.
■ 6. Section 64.6040 is revised to read
as follows:
§ 64.6040
device.
(b) No Provider shall charge, in any
Prison it serves, a per-minute rate for
Debit Calling, Prepaid Calling, or
Prepaid Collect Calling in excess of:
(1) $0.11;
(2) [Reserved]
(c) No Provider shall charge, in the
Jails it serves, a per-minute rate for
Collect Calling in excess of:
Collect rate
cap per MOU
as of June 20,
2016
Collect rate
cap per MOU
as of July 1,
2017
Collect rate
cap per MOU
as of July 1,
2018
$0.49
0.49
0.49
$0.36
0.33
0.32
$0.22
0.16
0.14
$0.22
0.16
0.14
■
Rates for calls involving a TTY
(a) No Provider shall levy or collect
any charge in excess of 25 percent of the
applicable per-minute rate for TTY-toTTY calls when such calls are
associated with Inmate Calling Services.
(b) No Provider shall levy or collect
any charge or fee for TRS-to-voice or
voice-to-TTY calls.
■ 7. Section 64.6060 is revised to read
as follows:
79179
(5) The number of TTY-based Inmate
Calling Services calls provided per
facility during the reporting period;
(6) The number of dropped calls the
reporting Provider experienced with
TTY-based calls; and
(7) The number of complaints that the
reporting Provider received related to
e.g., dropped calls, poor call quality and
the number of incidences of each by
TTY and TRS users.
(b) An officer or director of the
reporting Provider must certify that the
reported information and data are
accurate and complete to the best of his
or her knowledge, information, and
belief.
■ 8. Section 64.6070 is added to subpart
FF to read as follows:
§ 64.6070
Taxes and fees.
(a) No Provider shall charge any taxes
or fees to users of Inmate Calling
Services, other than those permitted
under § 64.6020, Mandatory Taxes,
Mandatory Fees, or Authorized Fees.
■ 9. Section 64.6080 is added to subpart
FF to read as follows:
§ 64.6060 Annual reporting and
certification requirement.
§ 64.6080
Charges.
(a) Providers must submit a report to
the Commission, by April 1st of each
year, regarding interstate, intrastate, and
international Inmate Calling Services for
the prior calendar year. The report shall
be categorized both by facility type and
size and shall contain:
(1) Current interstate, intrastate, and
international rates for Inmate Calling
Services;
(2) Current Ancillary Service Charge
amounts and the instances of use of
each;
(3) The Monthly amount of each Site
Commission paid;
(4) Minutes of use, per-minute rates
and ancillary service charges for video
visitation services;
No Provider shall impose a Per-Call or
Per-Connection Charge on a Consumer.
■ 10. Section 64.6090 is added to
subpart FF to read as follows:
PO 00000
Frm 00045
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
§ 64.6090
Per-Call, or Per-Connection
Flat-Rate Calling.
No Provider shall offer Flat-Rate
Calling for Inmate Calling Services.
■ 11. Section 64.6100 is added to
subpart FF to read as follows:
§ 64.6100 Minimum and maximum Prepaid
Calling account balances.
(a) No Provider shall institute a
minimum balance requirement for a
Consumer to use Debit or Prepaid
Calling.
(b) No Provider shall prohibit a
consumer from depositing at least $50
E:\FR\FM\18DER2.SGM
18DER2
79180
Federal Register / Vol. 80, No. 243 / Friday, December 18, 2015 / Rules and Regulations
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES2
per transaction to fund a Debit or
Prepaid Calling account.
■ 12. Section 64.6110 is added to
subpart FF to read as follows:
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:49 Dec 17, 2015
Jkt 238001
§ 64.6110 Consumer disclosure of Inmate
Calling Services rates.
Providers must clearly, accurately,
and conspicuously disclose their
interstate, intrastate, and international
rates and Ancillary Service Charges to
PO 00000
Frm 00046
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 9990
consumers on their Web sites or in
another reasonable manner readily
available to consumers.
[FR Doc. 2015–31252 Filed 12–17–15; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6712–01–P
E:\FR\FM\18DER2.SGM
18DER2
Agencies
[Federal Register Volume 80, Number 243 (Friday, December 18, 2015)]
[Rules and Regulations]
[Pages 79135-79180]
From the Federal Register Online via the Government Publishing Office [www.gpo.gov]
[FR Doc No: 2015-31252]
[[Page 79135]]
Vol. 80
Friday,
No. 243
December 18, 2015
Part II
Federal Communications Commission
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
47 CFR Part 64
Rates for Interstate Inmate Calling Services; Final Rule
Federal Register / Vol. 80 , No. 243 / Friday, December 18, 2015 /
Rules and Regulations
[[Page 79136]]
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION
47 CFR Part 64
[WC Docket No. 12-375; FCC 15-136]
Rates for Interstate Inmate Calling Services
AGENCY: Federal Communications Commission.
ACTION: Final rule.
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
SUMMARY: In this document, the Federal Communications Commission
(Commission) adopts comprehensive reforms of Inmate Calling Services,
regardless of the technology used to provide service, to ensure just
reasonable and fair rates as mandated by the Communications Act.
DATES: The rules in this document will become effective March 17, 2016,
and the Compliance Date for this Second Report and Order will be
January 19, 2016.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: Lynne Engledow, Wireline Competition
Bureau, Pricing Policy Division at (202) 418-1540 or at
Lynne.Engledow@fcc.gov.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: This is a summary of the Commission's Second
Report and Order, WC Docket 12-375, released November 5, 2015. The full
text of this document may be downloaded at the following Internet
Address: https://transition.fcc.gov/Daily_Releases/Daily_Business/2015/db1105/FCC-15-136A1.pdf. To request alternative formats for persons
with disabilities (e.g. accessible format documents, sign language,
interpreters, CARTS, etc.) send an email to fcc504@fcc.gov or call the
Commission's Consumer and Governmental Affairs Bureau at (202) 418-0530
or (202) 418-0432 (TTY).
I. Introduction
1. Twelve years have passed since Martha Wright of Washington, DC
petitioned this Commission for relief from exorbitant phone rates
charged by inmate calling service (ICS) providers, so that she might
afford telephone contact with her incarcerated grandson. For families,
friends, clergy, and attorneys to the over 2 million Americans behind
bars and 2.7 million children who have at least one parent behind bars,
maintaining phone contact has been made extremely difficult due to
prohibitively high charges on those calls. Family members report paying
egregious amounts, adding up to hundreds of dollars each month, just to
stay connected to incarcerated spouses, parents and children. For over
a decade, they have pleaded with this agency for help fighting these
excessive and unaffordable phone charges.
2. In the Report and Order, we grant relief, answer the call of
those millions of citizens seeking ICS reform, and adopt comprehensive
reform of interstate and intrastate ICS calls to ensure just,
reasonable and fair ICS rates as mandated by the Act. (Interstate
communication ``means communication or transmission (A) from any State,
Territory, or possession of the United States (other than the Canal
Zone), or the District of Columbia, to any State, Territory, or
possession of the United States (other than the Canal Zone), or the
District of Columbia. Consistent with our authority under the
Communications Act, this Order applies to all states and U.S.
territories including Puerto Rico, Guam, and the U.S. Virgin Islands.)
We follow these reforms with a Further Notice that recognizes there is
more work yet to be done. While the Commission prefers to rely on
competition and market forces to discipline prices, there is little
dispute that the ICS market is a prime example of market failure.
Market forces often lead to more competition, lower prices, and better
services. Unfortunately, the ICS market, by contrast, is characterized
by increasing rates, with no competitive pressures to reduce rates.
With respect to the consumers who pay the bills, ICS providers operate
as unchecked monopolists. The record indicates that, absent regulatory
intervention, ICS rates and associated ancillary fees likely will
continue to rise. After the adoption of interim interstate rate caps in
2013, there was hope that states would take a more active role in
reforming intrastate ICS rates and ancillary fees. While this has
occurred in a handful of states, such as Alabama, Minnesota, New
Jersey, and Ohio, the unfortunate reality is that many states have not
tackled reform and intrastate ICS rates have continued to increase
since the 2013 Order. 78 FR 67956, Nov. 13, 2013.
3. Given this market failure, the Commission has a duty to act to
fulfill our statutory mandate of ensuring that ICS rates are just,
reasonable, and fair. Ensuring that rates comply with the statute also
has several positive public interest benefits. Studies have shown that
family contact during incarceration reduces recidivism and allows
inmates to be more present parents for the 2.7 million children who
suffer when an incarcerated parent cannot afford to keep in touch. One
commenter tells us that ``[m]y family paid outrageous amounts, between
$300 and $400 a month for the 10 months while I was incarcerated in the
state of MD. Their savings were drained just so they could correspond
with their only daughter who was pregnant with their first grandchild
at the time.'' One mother writes: ``I pay 40 dollars a week for calls.
I can't afford them but it puts a smile on my kid's face;'' another
writes that her family has, at times, gone without food in order to pay
these phone charges, ``so we don't grow apart and so my kids feel like
they still have a father.'' These 2.7 million children are already
coping with the anxiety of having an incarcerated parent, and often
suffer additional economic and personal hardships that hinder their
performance in school. By charging inmates exorbitant phone rates, ICS
providers prevent incarcerated parents from maintaining a presence in
their children's lives through regular phone contact. The testimony of
a father in St. Cloud, Minnesota underscores the need for our efforts:
``I want to be able to raise my child even if it's over the phone for
the time being. I would love to be in her life as much as possible, but
it's hard to do so when the phone [price] is steadily climbing higher
and higher. I know I'm paying my debt to society for my crime, but I
need to stay in contact with family.''
4. Furthermore, inmates given access to regular phone contact with
family are less likely to return to jail or prison. A 2014 report by
the Department of Justice found that a staggering 75 percent of
individuals released from prison were rearrested within five years. Of
the inmates who do find success and reintegrate after release, many
credit phone contact and family support during their incarceration. As
one former inmate writes, ``The phone was my life line to that family
and they got me through it intact. I thank God that my family was able
to afford the phone calls. What happens to the families that can't? We
all end up paying for it.'' Incarceration costs taxpayers an average of
$31,000 per inmate per year. If telephone contact is made more
affordable, we will help ensure that former inmates are not sent home
as strangers, which reduces both their chances of returning to prison
or jail and the attendant burden on society of housing, feeding, and
caring for additional inmates.
5. Another commenter stresses how regular phone contact makes
prisons and jails safer spaces for inmates and officers alike:
I get to see my loved one once in every six months or so, and he
doesn't get any visitors apart from me, so calling daily helps him
retain his sanity. I think the connection he's given to his family
is really important; there are so many times that he's called really
[[Page 79137]]
angry at other inmates, saying that he just wanted to talk so that
he can cool down and not start a fight. If calls are made more
affordable, especially for indigent families, it may reduce prison
violence as well as make the prisons a safer place for [corrections
officers] to work in.
6. The record indicates that our interim interstate rate caps
increased call volumes, without compromising correctional facility
security requirements. Similarly, we expect our actions in this Order
to reduce rates and increase call volume, while ensuring that ICS
providers receive fair compensation and a reasonable return. Some
commenters have argued that lowering ICS rates will compromise security
in correctional facilities and fail to cover the cost of providing
calling services. Some have even argued the financial strain from rate
regulation could lead to correctional facilities banning inmate calls
altogether. However, we find these assertions unpersuasive and
unsupported by the record and our experience from the 2013 reforms.
7. While the actions taken to date have been positive in key
respects (e.g., lower interstate rates and increased interstate call
volume), more remains to be done. The Commission adopted interim
interstate rate caps, but over 80 percent of calls to and from
correctional facilities are intrastate, and were not subject to the
reforms of the 2013 Order. Throughout this proceeding, the Commission
has repeatedly called on states to reform inmate calling within their
jurisdictions, but rates remain egregiously high in over half the
states. The Commission has the legal authority to reform the rate
structure for all ICS calls, and herein we determine it is appropriate
and necessary to do so.
8. In addition, we commit to continue evaluating the impact of
these reforms and to conduct a review in two years to evaluate the
changes in the market and determine whether further refinements are
appropriate.
II. Executive Summary
9. In the Order, we adopt comprehensive reform of all aspects of
ICS to correct a market failure, foster market efficiencies, encourage
ongoing state reforms, and ensure that ICS rates and charges comply
with the Communications Act. As a threshold matter, we make clear that
the reforms adopted herein apply to ICS offered in all correctional
facilities, regardless of the technology used to deliver the service.
Specifically, we take the following steps, which together form a
comprehensive package of long-overdue reform to inmate calling
services:
Adopt tiered debit and prepaid rate caps that apply to all
interstate and intrastate ICS, as well as a tiered rate cap for collect
calling (which, after two years, will phase down to the rate caps
adopted for prepaid and debit calls);
Address payments to correctional institutions by excluding
site commission costs from our rate caps (we otherwise discourage, but
do not prohibit, ICS providers from sharing their profits and paying
site commissions to facilities);
Limit and cap ancillary service charges and address the
potential for loopholes and gaming, including third-party services,
thus addressing a disturbing trend in which ancillary service charges
increased exponentially and unfairly, to the detriment of inmates and
their families and in contravention of the statute;
Prohibit ICS prepaid calling account funding minimums and
establish an ICS prepaid calling account funding maximum limit;
Establish a periodic review of ICS reforms, recognizing
that further refinements may be appropriate as the marketplace
evolves--thus complementing the Further Notice we initiate today
(described in more detail below);
Make clear that the rate caps and reforms we adopt today
operate as a ceiling in states that have not enacted reforms with equal
or lower caps on rates and ancillary fees and that we will preempt
state laws that are inconsistent with the federal framework;
Take measures to address ongoing concerns with access to
ICS by inmates and their families with communications disabilities,
including requiring that the per-minute rates charged for TTY-to-TTY
calls be no more than 25 percent of the rates the providers charge for
traditional inmate calling services and that no provider shall levy or
collect any charge or fee for TRS-to-voice or voice-to-TTY calls;
Adopt a transition period for rate caps and ancillary
service charge reforms of March 17, 2016 for ICS provided in prisons
and June 20, 2016 for ICS provided in jails to enable providers time to
adjust contracts if necessary, given that the reforms adopted herein
constitute regulatory changes and thus may trigger change-in-law
provisions in existing ICS contracts;
Take measures to prevent possible gaming during the
transition to the new rules adopted herein;
Require annual reporting and certification by ICS
providers, to allow the Commission to ensure compliance and enable
monitoring of developments, and require the providers to be transparent
with regard to disclosure of their rates and policies;
Confirm that section 276 of the Act is technology neutral
and thus any service--regardless of name--that meets the definitional
criteria for ``inmate calling services'' is subject to our rules,
including the reforms adopted today; and
Make clear that ICS providers may seek waivers if they are
unable to receive fair compensation or request that the Commission
preempt inconsistent state laws, and encourage the Wireline Competition
Bureau to resolve such waivers within 90 days of submission of complete
information.
We adopt the following rate caps.
Table One
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Collect rate Collect rate Collect rate
Debit/prepaid cap per MOU as cap per MOU as cap per MOU as
Size and type of facility rate cap per of effective of July 1, of July 1,
MOU date 2017 2018
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
0-349 Jail ADP.................................. $0.22 $0.49 $0.36 $0.22
350-999 Jail ADP................................ 0.16 0.49 0.33 0.16
1,000+ Jail ADP................................. 0.14 0.49 0.32 0.14
All Prisons..................................... 0.11 0.14 0.13 0.11
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
We prohibit any ancillary service charges except for the following.
[[Page 79138]]
Table Two
------------------------------------------------------------------------
Permitted ancillary service charges and Monetary cap per use/
taxes instruction
------------------------------------------------------------------------
Applicable taxes and regulatory fees... Provider shall pass these
charges through to consumers
directly with no markup.
Automated payment fees................. $3.00.
Fees for single-call and related Provider shall directly pass
services, e.g., direct bill to mobile through third-party financial
phone without setting up an account. transaction fees with no
markup, plus adopted, per-
minute rate.
Live agent fee, i.e., phone payment or $5.95.
account set up with optional use of a
live operator.
Paper bill/statement fees (no charge $2.00.
permitted for electronic bills/
statements).
Prepaid account funding minimums and Prohibit prepaid account
maximums. funding minimums and prohibit
prepaid account funding
maximums under $50.
Third-party financial transaction fees, Provider shall pass this charge
e.g., MoneyGram, Western Union, credit through to end user directly,
card processing fees and transfers with no markup.
from third party commissary accounts.
------------------------------------------------------------------------
10. These reforms supersede the reforms adopted in the 2013 Order
and therefore will replace the interim interstate rate caps and cost-
based framework previously adopted. Accordingly, the extensive reforms
we adopt in this Order constitute material changes of law and may also
trigger contractual force majeure clauses. To comply with the new rules
we adopt herein, we therefore expect that ICS providers may need to
renegotiate many of their contracts with correctional facilities but
note that ICS rates in numerous states are already below our adopted
caps.
11. While the steps we take today are significant, our work is not
complete. With that in mind, in today's Further Notice, we seek
additional comment on rates for international calls, promoting
competition in the ICS industry, the benefits of a recurring Mandatory
Data Collection, as well as a requirement that ICS providers file their
ICS contracts with the Commission, video visitation, and other newer
technologies to increase ICS options, and seek additional comment on
the operations and economic impacts of providing those services as
experienced by end users, correctional facilities, and ICS providers.
III. Background
12. In 2003, Martha Wright and her fellow petitioners, current or
former prison inmates and their relatives and legal counsel (Wright
Petitioners or Petitioners), filed a petition seeking a rulemaking to
address high long-distance ICS rates. The petition sought to prohibit
exclusive ICS contracts and collect-call-only restrictions in
correctional facilities. In 2007, the Petitioners filed an alternative
rulemaking petition, asking the Commission to address high ICS rates by
requiring a debit-calling option in correctional facilities,
prohibiting per-call charges, and establishing rate caps for
interstate, interexchange ICS. The Commission sought and received
comment on both petitions (Wright Petitions).
13. In December 2012, in response to the Wright Petitions, the
Commission adopted a Notice of Proposed Rulemaking seeking comment on,
among other things, the proposals in the Wright Petitions. The 2012
NPRM, 78 FR 4369, Jan. 22, 2013, proposed ways to ``balance the goal of
ensuring reasonable ICS rates for end users with the security concerns
and expense inherent to ICS within the statutory guidelines of sections
201(b) and 276 of the Act.''
14. On August 9, 2013, the Commission adopted the Inmate Calling
Report and Order and FNPRM (2013 Order), finding that market forces
were not operating to ensure that interstate ICS rates were just,
reasonable, and fair. The Commission concluded that, in light of the
absence of competitive pressures working to keep rates just and
reasonable in the ICS market, the default of cost-based regulation
should apply. As such, the Commission focused on reforming interstate
site commission payments, rates, and ancillary service charges. The
Commission also determined that site commission payments ``were not
part of the cost of providing ICS and therefore not compensable in
interstate ICS rates.'' Analyzing data submitted into the record and
public data, the Commission adopted interim per-minute interstate ICS
safe harbor caps of $0.12 for debit and prepaid calls and $0.14 for
collect calls and hard rate caps of $0.21 for debit and prepaid calls
and $0.25 for collect calls. The Commission gave guidance to ICS
providers regarding the process for obtaining waivers of the interim
rate caps. The Commission also required that ancillary service charges
be cost-based. At the time, the Commission declined to address
intrastate ICS, noting instead that it had ``structured [its reforms]
in a manner to encourage . . . states to undertake reform and sought
comment on intrastate reforms as part of the FNPRM.'' Finally, the
record indicates that as a result of our interim interstate rate caps,
interstate call volumes have increased as much as 70 percent, while
interstate debit and prepaid rates have decreased, on average, 32
percent and interstate collect rates have decreased, on average, 44
percent.
15. To enable the Commission to enact ICS reform, the 2013 Order
adopted a Mandatory Data Collection requiring ICS providers to file
information regarding the costs of providing ICS, and an Annual
Reporting and Certification Requirement for ICS rates. The Commission
noted that the Mandatory Data Collection would help it ``develop a
permanent rate structure, which could include more targeted tiered
rates in the future.'' Through the data collected pursuant to the
Mandatory Data Collection, the Commission obtained significant cost and
operational data, including ancillary service charge cost data, from a
variety of ICS providers representing well over 85 percent of the ICS
market.
16. Prior to the effective date of the Order, the United States
Court of Appeals for the District of Columbia Circuit stayed three
rules adopted by the Commission pending resolution of the appeal,
including the rule requiring rates to be based on costs, the rule
adopting interim safe harbor rates, and the rule requiring ICS
providers to file annual reports and certifications. The court allowed
other aspects of the 2013 Order to take effect, including the interim
interstate rate caps and Mandatory Data Collection. Due to the partial
stay, the requirement that ancillary service charges be based on costs
did not go into effect. As a result,
[[Page 79139]]
there have been no reforms to ancillary service charges and fees and
they have continued to increase since the 2013 Order. The litigation
has been held in abeyance pending resolution of this Order.
17. Since adoption of the 2013 Order, the Commission has continued
to monitor the effects of its reforms on the ICS industry and pursue
additional reform, including holding a workshop entitled ``Further
Reform of Inmate Calling Services'' on July 9, 2014. The workshop
evaluated options for additional ICS reforms, discussed the effects of
the Order, the role ancillary service charges play in the ICS market,
the provision of ICS at different types of facilities, and
communications technologies beyond traditional payphone calling being
deployed in correctional facilities.
18. Second Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking. In October 2014,
the Commission adopted a Second FNPRM (79 FR 69682) and sought comment
on several proposals in the record urging comprehensive ICS reform. The
proposals the Commission sought comment on suggested a variety of ways
to deal with issues identified in the record, including rate caps, site
commission payments, and ancillary fees that were offered by various
entities with differing perspectives in addressing ICS reform. For
example, three ICS providers, GTL, Securus, and Telmate, jointly filed
a proposal to comprehensively reform all aspects of ICS. Several other
individual ICS providers, including CenturyLink and Pay Tel, submitted
their own proposals for reform. The Wright Petitioners, along with
several public interest groups, also urged the Commission to consider
its proposals for comprehensive reform. Finally, the Commission sought
comment on costs incurred by correctional facilities in the provision
of ICS and the data received in response to the Mandatory Data
Collection.
19. State Reforms. Several states have undertaken ICS reform since
the 2013 Order that reflect and are meant to address circumstances
specific to their jurisdiction. The Alabama Public Service Commission
(Alabama PSC), for example, adopted comprehensive ICS reforms that
include tiered intrastate rate caps as well as a restricted number of
ancillary service charges at caps it established. The Minnesota
Department of Corrections initiated a pilot program in a limited number
of correctional facilities in which a flat rate of $0.07 per minute is
charged for all local and long-distance debit calls, bringing the cost
of a 15-minute call to $1.05, plus applicable tax. New Jersey recently
entered into a new ICS contract lowering rates for all interstate and
intrastate calls from state prison facilities to $0.04348 a minute
effective August 25, 2015. The Ohio Department of Rehabilitation and
Correction reduced rates to $0.05 per minute for all ICS calls as of
April 1, 2015. In announcing its change, the Ohio Department of
Rehabilitation and Correction noted that ``[t]elephone calls are one of
the primary means of inmates maintaining connections with family and
loved ones during incarceration; maintaining these connections
positively influences behavior in prison and the likelihood an offender
will succeed upon release from prison.'' Inmates in the West Virginia
Division of Corrections now pay $0.032/minute for all domestic ICS. We
are pleased that some states have taken positive steps to reduce
intrastate rates but remain concerned that many intrastate rates remain
high and some have even increased following the 2013 Order. The actions
we take today embrace previous reforms and encourage additional states
to follow and enact more-tailored relief in their states. The framework
we adopt today acts as a ceiling to enable reforms, such as those
undertaken by New Jersey, Ohio, and West Virginia.
IV. Report and Order
A. Rate Caps That Comply With the Statute
20. In this section we adopt tiered rate caps for intrastate and
interstate ICS that will allow providers to continue to offer safe and
secure ICS while complying with the requirements of the Communications
Act. These rate caps will apply to jails, prisons and immigration
detention facilities, secure mental health facilities and juvenile
detention facilities.
21. A review of the record, including over 100 comments and
replies, costs reported in response to the Mandatory Data Collection,
and various ex parte filings, indicates that, notwithstanding our
interim caps on interstate rates, more work still must be done to bring
ICS rates in conformance with the mandates of the Communications Act.
The record demonstrates that many interstate rates are not ``just and
reasonable rates as required by Sections 201 and 202'' and that many
interstate and intrastate rates result in compensation that exceeds the
fair compensation permitted by section 276. The Commission's finding in
the 2013 Order that the marketplace alone has not ensured that ICS
rates are just, reasonable, and fair remains true today. Nor has the
risk of complaints filed under section 208, or enforcement actions
pursuant to section 201(b) or section 276, been sufficient to keep ICS
rates at levels that are just and reasonable and fairly compensatory.
We therefore act, pursuant to our statutory authority, to ensure that
ICS rates comply with the Communications Act, while balancing the
unique security needs related to providing telecommunications service
in correctional institutions and ensuring that ICS providers receive
fair compensation and a reasonable return on investment.
22. Specifically, we adopt a rate cap of $0.22/MOU for debit and
prepaid calls from jails with an ADP of 0-349; a $0.16/MOU cap for
debit and prepaid calls from jails with an ADP of 350-999; and a $0.14/
MOU cap for debit and prepaid calls from jails with an ADP of 1,000 or
more. Debit and prepaid calls from prisons will be capped at a rate of
$0.11/MOU. Collect calls from jail facilities will be capped at $0.49/
MOU and collect calls from prison facilities will be capped at $0.14/
MOU until July 1, 2017, and then transition down on an annual basis to
the applicable debit/prepaid rate cap as described herein.
Table Three
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Collect rate Collect rate Collect rate
Debit/prepaid cap per MOU as cap per MOU as cap per MOU as
Size and type of facility rate cap per of effective of July 1, of July 1,
MOU date 2017 2018
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
0-349 Jail ADP.................................. $0.22 $0.49 $0.36 $0.22
350-999 Jail ADP................................ 0.16 0.49 0.33 0.16
1,000+ Jail ADP................................. 0.14 0.49 0.32 0.14
All Prisons..................................... 0.11 0.14 0.13 0.11
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
[[Page 79140]]
23. In the subsections that follow, we describe our methodology for
adopting these rate caps. Specifically, we: (1) Discuss the decision to
adopt a tiered structure that distinguishes between jails and prisons,
and, within jails, based upon ADP, (2) describe the reasoning for
adopting the specified tiers, (3) describe the methodology and analysis
supporting the specific rate caps adopted, using a carefully considered
combination of analysis of the Mandatory Data Collection (including
evidence suggesting that some providers submitted inflated cost data),
successful reform in certain states, experience with the interim rate
caps, and other data in the voluminous record of this proceeding, (4)
explain the need for a temporary, separate rate for collect calls,
which will phase out over a two-year period to equalize the rate for
these calls with those of debit/prepaid calls, (5) reject per-call/per-
connection charges and flat-rate calling as inherently unjust,
unreasonable, and unfair in contravention of the statute, and (6)
explain our legal authority to adopt these reforms.
1. Tiered Structure Distinguishing Between Jails and Prisons
24. Before determining the specific amount of any rate caps, a key
question before us is the appropriate rate structure for ICS--i.e.,
whether there should be a single unitary rate for inmate calling
services regardless of the facility type or size. We find in this Order
that the record supports distinguishing between the type of facility
(jails vs. prisons) as well as, for jails, tiering based on the size of
the facility.
a. Justification for Separate Tiers
25. In both the 2013 FNPRM (78 FR 68005) and Second FNPRM, the
Commission sought comment on rate tiering. In the Second FNPRM, the
Commission also sought comment on the appropriate definition of
``prison'' and ``jail,'' and on the potential suitability of rate
tiering based on differences between jails and prisons as well as
population size. As discussed below, there was substantial record
support for such an approach.
26. Background. Some commenters support differentiating rates
between different facility types or sizes. For example, Petitioners
assert that the ``cost of providing service in these large facilities
is substantially less than the cost of providing service in small
jails, and that ICS providers can serve these larger facilities with
less administrative costs.'' Other commenters assert that
``characteristics unique to different types of facilities'' should lead
to rate tiering. Some commenters contend that it costs more to provide
ICS in smaller jails than it does in larger jails. These parties argue
that a one-size-fits-all rate cap will not work, ignores the record and
likely will lead to a violation of sections 201 and 276 of the Act. We
note that the Alabama PSC recently adopted rate tiers tied to facility
type, with separate rates for jails and prisons.
27. The Los Angeles Sheriff's Department advocates that the
Commission ``resist the temptation to set uniform rates'' because the
differences in security requirements, inmates, age, infrastructure and
maintenance needs of facilities must be accounted for in the
Commission's decision-making process.'' The California State Sheriff's
Association echoes these concerns, explaining that in California, the
smallest jail can hold a maximum of 14 inmates, while the largest jail
can hold a maximum of over 14,000 inmates, and contends that accounting
for these differences ``is much more important and realistic than
attempting to craft a single `solution' for uniformity's sake.'' NCIC
also supports tiering in order to ``balance the needs of inmates, their
families, correction facilities and ICS providers.''
28. Moreover, some commenters assert that, without tiering,
providers serving small- to medium-sized jails ``would likely be forced
out of the market, particularly if the larger companies cross-subsidize
between low-cost (Prison) and high-cost (Jail) facilities'' because it
is more costly to providers to serve smaller facilities (as confirmed
by our analysis of the Mandatory Data Collection). Additionally, there
is evidence that some large ICS providers refuse to bid on contracts to
serve only smaller institutions--suggesting again that the cost
structure of serving smaller institutions is higher than that of larger
institutions.
29. Other commenters, however, disagree with a tiered rate approach
and counter that the Commission should continue to impose unitary rate
caps, similar to the current, interim rate caps. These commenters
contend that unitary rates are less complex to understand and to
administer, and that no real difference exists between the cost of
serving jails and prisons. For instance, GTL and CenturyLink contend
that ``there is no clean proxy for cost that could be relied upon to
create tiers.'' Additionally, some commenters argue that adopting tiers
based on a prison/jail distinction would be arbitrary, especially as
many large providers serve both prisons and jails. Securus claims that
``to adopt vastly different calling rates based on that empty [jails
vs. prisons] distinction would constitute dissimilar treatment of
customers that plainly are similarly situated,'' which it asserts is
``unjustifiable.''
30. Discussion. Based on the record and market evidence, we find
that tiering based on jail versus prison is appropriate, and therefore
reject proposals that we should adopt a unitary rate similar to the
unitary rate caps adopted in the 2013 Order.
31. In the 2013 Order, the Commission found it appropriate to adopt
interim unitary rates for a number of reasons. First, the Commission
observed the challenges to setting interim rates, including the fact
that although the Commission relied on the best data available to it at
the time, that data represented a very small subset of data, and
included cost data from locations with varying cost and call volume
characteristics. Second, the Commission noted that it considered
setting different rate caps based on the size or type of correctional
facility, but stated that ``the record contains conflicting assertions
as to what those distinctions should be.'' Instead, the Commission
adopted interim interstate rate caps ``for correctional facilities
generally,'' ``based on the highest cost data available in the record,
which [it] anticipated will ensure fair compensation for providers
servicing jails and prisons alike.'' Finally, the Commission noted that
unitary rates were the focus of the original petition for rulemaking
and the focus of the majority of comments at that time. Upon release of
that item, the Commission adopted the Mandatory Data Collection to
``enable [it] to take further action to reform rates, including
developing a permanent cap or safe harbor for interstate rates, as well
as to inform our evaluation of other rate reform options in the Further
Notice.'' The responses to the Mandatory Data Collection have greatly
expanded the cost data available to us for analysis.
32. We conclude that adopting tiered interstate and intrastate
rates accounts for the differences in costs to ICS providers serving
smaller, higher-cost facilities, such as the vast majority of jails. A
similar concern applies to the potential for over-compensating ICS
providers serving larger, lower cost facilities, such as very large
jails and prisons. We agree with those commenters who assert that the
$0.20 and $0.24 rate caps proposed in the Joint Provider Proposal could
result in excessive profits for the largest providers to the detriment
of end users who would have to pay inflated rates far
[[Page 79141]]
above the providers' costs. For example, in the public portion of its
cost data filing Securus noted that its overall cost per minute across
all of its ICS contracts is $0.1776. GTL similarly provided its overall
cost per minute across all ICS contracts, which it estimated at
$0.1341. These averaged, self-reported, costs are well below the $0.20
and $0.24 rate caps proposed by these same providers in the Joint
Provider Proposal.
33. The record, and our analysis of costs reported in response to
the Mandatory Data Collection, support rate tiering because, holding
other factors constant, the costs to serve prisons are lower than to
serve jails. This is not surprising. Prisons typically have more
stable, long-term inmate populations. For example, there is less than
one percent inmate churn in prisons per week compared to an average of
58 percent inmate churn in jails. The record suggests that higher churn
rates increase costs to process and grant a new inmate access to
calling services, and also when an inmate exits a facility. The record
also indicates that prison inmates make fewer but longer calls and
providers appear to incur fewer bad debt costs when serving prisons.
34. We also find that economies of scale, such as the recovering of
fixed ICS costs over a larger number of inmates, support the tiering
approach we adopt today. In the 2013 Order, the Commission noted that
unit or average costs of providing ICS were decreasing as scale
increased because of, for example, centralized application of security
measures and ``the ability to centrally provision across multiple
facilities.'' More generally, providers of ICS typically incur a range
of costs that do not scale with volume, sometimes known as fixed costs.
For example, the cost of a calling center is largely shared over a
provider's entire operations, so the unit costs of the calling center
fall quickly as call volumes increase. Similarly, the cost of
connecting a facility to the ICS provider's network increases at a much
lower rate when minutes of use increase. Indeed, in general, the
incremental cost of a minute of use is almost zero. The Kansas
Department of Corrections echoes these findings, stating in its support
for rate tiering that ``[t]he cost to provide an ICS is largely driven
by the size of a facility and length of stay. Larger facilities benefit
from the economies of scale that allows agencies and ICS providers to
spread the cost among a larger population.'' Pay Tel also reports that
there are material fixed costs in providing ICS which can be
distributed across larger facilities, like prisons, more readily than
smaller facilities such as jails. Indeed, many ICS providers currently
offer service to multiple facilities under one contract, reflecting the
benefits of centralizing fixed costs across a larger base of customers.
Lastly, ongoing industry consolidation supports our finding that there
are economies of scale in the provision of ICS, i.e., the incentive to
become more efficient through scale is an incentive for providers to
enter into mergers.
35. Recent state reforms also support tiering. Indeed, the Alabama
PSC recently adopted rate tiers tied to facility type with separate
rates adopted for jails and prisons. In December 2014, the Alabama PSC
adopted a rate structure that ``provides lower rates [for prisons] in
recognition that the per-minute costs for service in prisons is lower
than it is for jails.'' In order ``to ensure ample opportunity to
correct any funding shortfalls resulting from potential reductions in
site commissions,'' the adopted rate caps included a two-year phase-
down period from $0.30/minute to $0.25/minute for collect and debit/
prepaid calling from jails and $0.25/minute to $0.21/minute for debit/
prepaid calling from prisons, while the prison collect rate stays at
the initial $0.25/minute rate cap.
36. We disagree with assertions that a tiered rate structure would
be difficult for the Commission to administer, for ICS providers to
implement, and for correctional officials to oversee. Those commenters
who make such assertions already charge different rates across
different ICS contracts and provide no real evidence or support for why
rate tiers would be any more difficult or challenging than their
current approaches.
37. For all of these reasons, we conclude that adopting rate tiers
based on facility type as well as size, or ADP, allows us to recognize
the differences in the costs of serving facilities of different types
as well as providing multiple checks to prevent gaming or manipulation
as discussed below. Tiering will limit ``the impact of the higher rates
to those facilities most in need, while ensuring that the vast majority
of ICS calls are charged at a rate commensurate with the cost of
providing the ICS service.''
b. Determination of Facility Type and Average Daily Population
38. Defining Jails and Prisons. Given that our rates will differ
for prisons and jails, it is necessary to define these key terms with
specificity. The Commission sought comment on defining the terms
``prison'' and ``jail'' in the Second FNPRM. Subsequent to the Second
FNPRM, several commenters provided suggested definitions. We have
considered these submissions and adopt the following definitions.
39. Specifically, for purposes of this proceeding a jail is defined
as the facility of a local, state, or federal law enforcement agency
that is used primarily to hold individuals who are: (1) Awaiting
adjudication of criminal charges, (2) post-conviction and committed to
confinement for sentences of one year or less, or (3) post-conviction
and are awaiting transfer to another facility. The term also includes
city, county or regional facilities that have contracted with a private
company to manage day-to-day operations; privately-owned and operated
facilities primarily engaged in housing city, county or regional
inmates; and facilities used to detain individuals pursuant to a
contract with U.S. Immigration and Customs Enforcement (ICE) and
facilities operated by ICE. For purposes of this proceeding a prison is
defined as a facility operated by a territorial, state, or federal
agency that is used primarily to confine individuals convicted of
felonies and sentenced to terms in excess of one year. The term also
includes public and private facilities that provide housing to other
agencies such as the State Departments of Correction and the Federal
Bureau of Prisons; and facilities that would otherwise fall under the
definition of a jail but in which the majority of inmates are post-
conviction or are committed to confinement for sentences of longer than
one year.
40. Facility or Institution. The record indicates concern that some
ICS providers may try to take advantage of the rate tiering structure
we adopt in this Order by increasing the number of ``facilities'' in
which they are allowed to charge the higher rate caps adopted for
smaller jails above. For example, ICS providers may do this, commenters
explain, by seeking to divide a detention facility into sub-units, such
as wards or wings. The Commission sought comment on these possibilities
in the Second FNPRM. Comments received in response confirmed that
concerns that providers might try to game our rules were justified.
Such gaming would be contrary to this Order, and would serve to
frustrate the underlying purposes of sections 201 and 276 of the
Communications Act. It would allow providers to appear as though they
are serving smaller jails than they actually are, even though they
achieve economies of scale by combining multiple small facilities under
a single contract, because they are able to centralize services, like
call monitoring
[[Page 79142]]
and recording, thereby reducing their overall costs. In order to
establish and maintain just, reasonable, and fair ICS compensation, we
must consider these issues and take steps to ensure that our adopted
tiered rate caps cannot be undone by gaming.
41. As such, we find that a jail, as defined above, and a prison,
as defined above, cannot be divided into multiple wings, units, or
wards by, for example, for the purpose of taking advantage of our
tiered rate caps. If interested parties believe such gaming is
occurring they may bring the issue to the Commission's attention, at
which time the Commission will review the totality of the circumstances
(e.g., treatment of the facility under state law, relevant contracts,
physical attachment or proximity of units, etc.) to determine whether
unlawful gaming has occurred.
42. Average Daily Population for Jails. As an initial matter, for
purposes of the reforms adopted in this Order, the initial average
daily population will be the sum of all inmates in a facility each day
in the 12-month period prior to the effective date of this Order
divided by the number of days in the year. This definition is
consistent with that used by the Department of Justice's Bureau of Jail
Statistics. We note that correctional institutions often publicly
report their ADP. This publicly-reported population data should be
used, where available, to determine the appropriate ADP for a facility.
Going forward, when the relevant ADP is not publicly reported,
beginning with January 31, 2017, the ADP will be calculated on a
calendar year basis as the sum of all inmates in a facility each day
between January 1 and December 31 of the previous year, divided by the
number of days in the year. The applicable ADP will then be determined
as of January 31 of each year pursuant to the ADP from the previous
year and will remain in effect throughout that year. Consistent with
this approach, if a correctional facility adds a new building or wing
to a facility, the inmate population of the new wing will not be
accounted for immediately. Rather, the inmate population of a new
building or wing will first be considered in the calculations for ADP
to be applied in the following year. For example, if a new wing is
established anytime between January 1, 2017 and December 31, 2017, its
inmate population during this time frame will be included in the ADP to
be applied on January 31, 2018. We find this to be the most
administratively efficient and feasible option, rather than potentially
having numerous rate changes during a calendar year. New buildings or
wings may not be filled immediately, and it may take some time before
population levels in a newly-established wing increase enough to push
the facility as a whole into a new tier. We find these detailed
definitions are necessary to ensure that end users are charged just,
reasonable, and fair rates and that ICS providers receive fair
compensation for the costs they incur in providing ICS to smaller and
larger facilities.
43. Categorization of Certain High-Cost Facilities. In the Second
FNPRM the Commission sought comment on suggestions that it either
exclude from any adopted rate caps what are reported to be high-cost
facilities, such as juvenile detention facilities or secure mental
health facilities, or provide a blanket waiver for such facilities.
While the Commission did not request that providers separately
calculate and report their costs for providing service to secure mental
health facilities or juvenile detention facilities outside of jails or
prisons in response to the Mandatory Data Collection, we agree with
commenters that these facilities may be more costly to serve due to the
smaller number of inmates. This is also consistent with our analysis
above. We therefore conclude that the costs of providing ICS to
juvenile detention facilities and secure mental health facilities are
more akin to providing service to jail facilities. To the extent that
juvenile detention facilities and secure mental health facilities
operate outside of jail or prison institutions, they will be subject to
the jail rate caps adopted herein.
2. Tiers for Jails
44. After placing issues relating to the Mandatory Data Collection
out for public comment, the Bureau reviewed written comments, met with
interested parties, and adopted a template for submission of required
data in the Mandatory Data Collection. In it, the Bureau directed ICS
providers to document applicable costs and fees by ``contract size.''
Potential contract size categories for jails include 0-99, 100-349,
349-999, and 1000 ADP and greater, and potential categories for prisons
include 1-4999, 5000-19,999, and 20,000 ADP and greater.
45. The Commission sought comment on proposed rate tiering in the
Second FNPRM. Pay Tel asserts that it supports three rate tiers, one
for ``small-to-medium sized jails (less than 350 ADP) based on
`demonstrated operational and functional differences between prisons
and jails--and the cost differences associated with [the] provision of
ICS therein.''' Petitioners support a two-tiered structure and suggest
rate caps for facilities with 0-349 ADP and facilities with 350 and
over ADP in order to take into account the ``alleged higher costs
incurred by small jails. The Joint Provider Proposal does not favor any
rate tiers. Securus asserts that if the Commission adopts a tiered rate
structure, ``the tiers should be defined in a way that account[s] not
only for ADP but also differences in the investment required to serve a
site. . . . And, as Securus previously has stated, ADP must be very
closely defined such that carriers cannot game the system in the way
that they report those figures.''
46. In this Order we adopt rate tiers based on the following ADP
for jails: 0-349, 350-999, and 1,000 and greater. We adopt these rate
tiers for jails because we find that they most closely resemble the
breakdown between small-to-medium jails, large jails, and very large,
or mega-jails. We have decided not to include a 0-99 ADP breakdown in
the rate tiers in part because, according to the Bureau of Justice
Statistics, jails with an ADP under 99 make up less than 10 percent of
the inmate population. We also believe that adopting fewer tiers than
those requested in response to the Mandatory Data Collection responds
to comments in the record expressing concern over potential confusion
and burden of multiple rates. By adopting these tiers for jails, we
conclude that our rate caps will most closely conform to the costs as
filed in the record. As a group, jails are more varied than prisons
and, as we have discussed herein, there are economies of scale to be
gained as facility size increases. Finally, as discussed below, the
data received in response to the Mandatory Data Collection support
these tiers.
47. Below we explain how we have determined that our prescribed
rates will allow efficient providers to recover their costs. We rely
principally upon: (1) Analysis of data received in response to the
Mandatory Data Collection, which shows that firms operating efficiently
would earn substantial profits under our prescribed rates, (2) evidence
suggesting that providers' reported costs in response to the mandatory
data collection are overstated, and (3) other evidence in the record,
including ICS providers' provision of service in jurisdictions with
rates lower than those we prescribe here.
3. Determination of Specific Rate Caps
48. Having determined the basic structure of rate caps, we describe
the methodology for the specific rate caps within that structure.
Specifically, we find that the following rate caps will ensure that ICS
rates are just,
[[Page 79143]]
reasonable, and fair for inmates, their families and loved ones, as
well as the ICS providers, and will incorporate the costs associated
with the necessary security protocols: $0.22/MOU for debit and prepaid
calls from jails with an ADP of 0-349; $0.16/MOU for debit and prepaid
calls from jails with an ADP of 350-999; and $0.14/MOU for debit and
prepaid calls from jails with an ADP of 1,000 or more. Debit and
prepaid calls from prisons will be capped at a rate of $0.11/MOU.
Collect calls from jails will be capped at $0.49/MOU and collect calls
from prisons will be capped at $0.14/MOU until July 1, 2017, and then
transition down to the appropriate debit/prepaid rate cap.
a. Marketplace Evidence of Rates in Certain States
49. Evidence of rates at the state level generally provides further
support that the rate caps we adopt today allow sufficient room for
providers to earn a fair profit. As noted above, Ohio eliminated site
commissions and reduced ICS rates by 75 percent to $0.05 for Ohio
Department of Rehabilitation and Correction (ODRC) facilities. West
Virginia's Division of Corrections recently reviewed bids without
regard to site commissions offered by the bidders (i.e., the DOC did
not take site commissions into account in deciding the winning bidder).
New Jersey recently awarded an ICS contract for state prisons that
eliminated site commission payments and reduced rates below $0.05 per
minute, yet the winning bidder, GTL, reported to the Commission average
2012 through 2013 ICS costs of [BEGIN CONFIDENTIAL] [END CONFIDENTIAL].
The Pennsylvania Department of Corrections (DOC) contracted with
Securus at a $0.059 per-minute rate for all ICS and the elimination of
all ancillary fees, while offering a 35 percent site commission, even
though Securus reported to the Commission that its average cost of
providing ICS over 2012 and 2013 was [BEGIN CONFIDENTIAL] [END
CONFIDENTIAL]. Similarly, in New Hampshire, the state DOC lowered
intrastate rates to less than $0.06 per minute with a 20 percent site
commission. That providers bid for these contracts, and supply ICS at
rates consistent with these constraints, strongly suggests that
efficient providers can provide ICS at rates closer to $0.05 per
minute--less than half of our lowest rate cap of $0.11 per minute. This
is not surprising, as a per-minute rate of approximately $0.05 per
minute approximates the lowest average per-minute costs reported to us.
We observe that it is unlikely that any provider would supply any state
if the rates allowed in those states did not at least cover the
incremental costs of supplying each of those states, which further
suggests that reported costs may be inflated. We also note that no
provider clearly argued that such rate levels are the result of cross-
subsidization, and there is no data in the record to support such a
conclusion. While one provider made statements unsupported by data that
might be so interpreted, those statements are too vague to evaluate.
b. Analysis of Data Received in Response to the Mandatory Data
Collection
50. Rate Methodology. In the 2013 Order, the Commission adopted the
Mandatory Data Collection to enable it ``to take further action to
reform rates, including developing a permanent cap or safe harbor for
interstate rates, as well as to inform our evaluation of other rate
reform options in the Further Notice.'' In 2014, the Wireline
Competition Bureau (Bureau) developed a template and related
instructions for ICS providers to use in responding to the Mandatory
Data Collection. The Commission also provided notice of the data
collection, its due date, and information on contacting Bureau staff
available to answer specific questions on how to comply with the filing
requirement and the template and instructions. The instructions,
template, and other related material were posted on the Commission's
Web site, and the data collection due date was announced by Public
Notice which was also published in the Federal Register, 79 FR 35956,
Nov. 21, 2014. Responsive data were received in August 2014.
51. The Commission directed the Bureau to create the template in a
manner intended to allow a provider to include all costs incurred in
the provision of ICS. Without limiting or restricting costs or cost
categories, the Bureau directed providers to report their ICS-related
costs for telecommunications, equipment, and security, as well as any
costs not captured in these categories (i.e., ``other costs''). The
Commission directed providers to submit the data for fiscal years 2012,
2013, and 2014, which provided the two most recent years of actual data
and one year of partial actual and partial forecasted data. Providers
were required to report intrastate, interstate and international ICS
cost data in the aggregate for debit, prepaid, and collect calling
services. For each service, providers were required to identify which
costs were direct or common, and to allocate costs by facility type and
size. Providers also submitted call volume data (MOU and number of
calls) for each category. The Commission received data filings from 14
of the 25 anticipated ICS provider respondents. We estimate that the 14
responding providers together represent over 90 percent of the market.
52. The debit and prepaid rate caps we adopt are based on 2012 and
2013 data submitted by the 14 responding providers. The caps rely on
the 2012 and 2013 data because it represents actual, rather than
projected, data, and allows averaging across the two years to account
for cost variations that may occur between the years. Costs per minute
were calculated using a weighted average per minute cost (which is the
same as dividing aggregate costs (i.e., the entirety of all costs
reported by the providers for any category) by aggregate minutes of use
in that category). This prevents small outliers from having a
disproportionate impact on our analysis.
53. Based on the record and our analysis described below, we
believe the applicable rate caps will ensure just, reasonable and fair
compensation for ICS. We have relied on the cost data and allocations
as submitted by ICS providers in calculating these rate caps. We note
that the providers cost data reflect their determinations about how to
allocate certain common costs, such as call centers and back-office
operations. It is generally understood that an economically rational
provider will serve a facility if it can recover its incremental cost
of doing so, which the record and our analysis indicate will be the
case. We take the data at face value, even though the analysis shows
that there is significant evidence--both from our own analysis and
commenters' critiques--suggesting that the reported costs are
overstated. We also find support in the record evidence of increased
demand and additional scale efficiencies, which are not included in our
quantitative analysis. Our analysis and the record evidence support our
conclusion that efficient providers would be able to operate profitably
under our rate caps.
54. Discussion and Analysis. Based on the record and our own
analysis described below, we find that our prescribed rate caps as
outlined above are more than sufficient to allow providers to recover
efficiently-incurred ICS costs (excluding reported commissions).
55. The record supports our conclusion. Coleman Bazelon, economics
consultant for the Wright Petitioners, analyzed our rate caps and
concluded that they ``will largely cover the individual ICS providers'
costs in
[[Page 79144]]
providing service.'' [BEGIN CONFIDENTIAL] [END CONFIDENTIAL] The
Bazelon economic analysis does not take into account the evidence that
lower rates will spur demand, such that the vast majority of the
industry costs will be covered by the rates adopted today.
56. ICSolutions, an ICS provider, states that it ``can comply with
the proposed rules'' and notes that this ``strongly suggests that any
entity failures in the industry are likely a result of inefficient
operations.'' NCIC also supports our rate caps. Praeses ``believes that
Providers will generally be able to provide services pursuant to these
rate caps at a profit.'' Praeses also reports that interstate call
volume and resulting revenue have increased since our 2013 interim
reform, with facilities operated by its clients seeing approximately 76
percent interstate call volume increases and overall interstate revenue
growth of approximately twelve percent. This is unsurprising, as
reduced prices typically lead to higher volume. ICSolutions reports
seeing call volumes increase ``by as much as 150%, and revenues
increase by about 30%'' when it implements lower call rates. In
addition, our rate caps are generally higher than rates that have been
adopted in several states that have undertaken reform and there is no
evidence in the record that such rates have made provision of ICS
unprofitable. Also, nothing in the record suggests that states that
have adopted such reforms are different from those states that have not
adopted reform with respect to either costs or revenues.
57. Our own analysis likewise shows that the rate caps will permit
just, reasonable, and fair recovery for the provision of ICS. Our
approach is conservative in its analysis of both costs and call volumes
(and hence revenues). It includes all the reported data, assumes they
do not overstate costs, and takes no account of likely increases in
call volumes that our rates would induce, thereby understating expected
revenues. This analysis thus likely reflects a worst-case scenario,
and, as discussed below, even in the worst-case scenario, our rates are
fair and reasonable.
58. Costs. Our analysis of costs supports our conclusion that
efficient providers will be assured just, reasonable, and fair
compensation under our rate caps. In particular, based on the unaudited
costs for 2012 and 2013 reported by the 14 respondents to the
Commission's Mandatory Data Collection, the lowest rate cap we
prescribe ($0.11) is greater than the average per minute cost of each
of the more efficient reporting providers. Two of these providers are
quite small, and operate in relatively small jails only. As a result,
as discussed below, the expected efficient cost of these small
providers on a per minute basis is likely higher than the efficient
costs larger reporting providers face, which implies that larger
providers should also be able to operate at a profit at our prescribed
prices. We recognize that some providers may supply a range of services
that go beyond ICS, and the prices that they charge may be used to
cross-subsidize these services. However, we do not consider it
appropriate for non-ICS services, such as location-monitoring, to be
paid for by inmates and their families and friends through ICS rates.
59. Further, we find that providers reporting high costs could
recover those costs and receive just, reasonable, and fair compensation
under our rate caps through increased efficiencies. Our analysis
suggests that providers generally may have been over inclusive in
reporting their costs and that the supply of ICS is not fully
competitive, implying that the adopted rate caps are conservative. We
also note that no providers have submitted evidence that their higher
costs may be attributable to higher-quality or more technologically-
advanced ICS.
60. Other evidence reinforces our view that respondents' reported
costs may in some cases exceed economic costs, and lead us to conclude
that our prescribed rate caps will allow efficient firms to recover
their economic costs, including a reasonable return. For example, the
average per-paid minute cost of each of the seven largest firms
substantially exceeds the average per-paid minute average cost of each
of three smaller providers. This data point suggests these larger firms
are either economically inefficient or that they overstated their costs
of ICS provision. On one hand, if there were economies of scale or
constant returns to scale in production of calls or call minutes of
use, then larger firms would have lower or the same average costs as
the smaller firms, implying that these larger firms' reported costs are
above efficient levels. On the other hand, if there were diseconomies
of scale (that is, the average per-minute cost rises with MOU volumes),
then these firms are inefficiently large (they would be more effective
broken up into smaller firms), and we should not subsidize that
anomaly.
61. More generally, we find above that average costs should fall
with the provider's size. However, the reported data (implausibly) show
only a very weak negative relationship between average costs and the
number of calls or MOU. Similarly, the data (again implausibly) do not
support a priori assumptions about underlying costs. For example,
regression analysis indicates that the firms' costs were highly
correlated with different measures of MOU, type of call, and facilities
serviced. However, in most specifications the coefficients associated
with the MOU and call variables were implausible: they were typically
well above the expected marginal cost of an additional MOU. Further, in
some specifications, the differences between the marginal costs of
different types of calls were implausibly large and statistically
significant. Both of these facts (the lack of scale economies in call
production and minutes of use and oddities about reported marginal
costs) suggest that the data do not reflect the actual economic costs
of supply and lead us to doubt the extent to which reported costs
accurately reflect efficient costs. Additionally, reinforcing our view
that reported costs are inefficiently high, there is evidence that some
of the providers' costs include services that are not directly related
to the provision of ICS. In short, all these observations make it all
the more likely that our prescribed rate caps would allow an efficient
provider to earn economic profits.
62. There is also evidence that competition to supply ICS may not
always be robust, which in turn suggests providers are able to earn
more than economic costs, and if faced with lower revenues, may remain
profitable. The most important evidence in this last respect is that
the providers' unaudited cost data show that roughly similarly situated
providers have substantially different costs. This not only suggests
that the higher cost providers are unlikely to be economically
efficient, but also that if they were to operate more efficiently, they
would have no difficulties in recovering their economic costs. For
example, a lack of robust competition would explain why the reported
cost data does not seem reflective of underlying costs (a result that
is inconsistent with effective competition). Analysis of that data also
finds a tight relationship between costs and output levels, both when
commissions are included and excluded. This suggests a high degree of
homogeneity in the industry between reported costs (with and without
commissions) and output. One might expect such results if all bids for
ICS were either competitive or non-competitive, but, as noted, other
aspects
[[Page 79145]]
of the cost data are inconsistent with competition, and other evidence
suggests competition, if it exists, is not found everywhere.
63. Two of the six smallest responding providers when ranked by
paid MOU would earn substantial imputed profits at our prescribed
rates. For example, over 2012 and 2013, [BEGIN CONFIDENTIAL] [END
CONFIDENTIAL] had an average per paid minute cost of $0.05 (and a
similar average per all minute cost) when rounded to the nearest $0.05,
earning imputed profits of well over 200 percent. Similarly, in 2012
and 2013, [BEGIN CONFIDENTIAL] [END CONFIDENTIAL] had an average per-
paid minute cost of $0.10 when rounded to the nearest $0.05, earning
imputed profits in excess of 100 percent.
64. In contrast, our conservative approach imputed reductions in
providers' ability to recover costs under our initial rate caps to
seven of the reporting providers, but we find that all of these
providers would be highly profitable if their cost structures resembled
those of the two small efficient firms we identified. Four of these are
among the six smallest responding providers. Each reported average per-
paid minute costs over 2012 and 2013 of $0.25 or higher. That is, in
all cases their average per-paid minute costs were more than two and a
half times, and in some cases several multiples of, the highest paid
MOU average cost of the two small providers with imputed profits.
Consequently, if these four providers' average costs were halved, so
that they still exceeded those of the two small providers with imputed
profits, then all four would operate at a profit given our conservative
revenue assumptions. The remaining three providers with imputed
reductions in cost recovery are considerably larger than the two small
providers with imputed profits discussed above, and more than one
supplies services in prisons as well as jails. Yet, each has an average
per-paid minute cost that is at least three times as high as that of
[BEGIN CONFIDENTIAL] [END CONFIDENTIAL] (which we found to have large
imputed profits). Again, if these providers' costs were considerably
closer to, but still well above those of [BEGIN CONFIDENTIAL] [END
CONFIDENTIAL], then they would be able to earn profits while charging
rates consistent with our prescribed rate caps. In the two subsequent
years, providers' ability to recover costs would change, but in all
cases if these providers were as efficient as the two efficient
providers discussed above, they would earn an economic profit in all of
the years discussed.
65. Revenue. Turning to revenue, our analysis likewise demonstrates
that our rate caps permit fair, reasonable, and just compensation. Once
again, we take the provider's data as filed despite the evidence that
they are overstated. Moreover, even assuming the same call volumes as
experienced in 2012 and 2013, no other revenue sources, and no improved
efficiency in service provision, we can impute in the initial year that
all providers, if operating efficiently, would be profitable under our
prescribed rate caps. With more realistic assumptions (greater call
volumes, revenues from ancillary services, and productivity
improvements), it is likely that any provider facing imputed revenue
reductions in the range of 10 percent would remain profitable even if
its reported costs were not overstated (and we find to the contrary).
For example, for the reasons described below and based on record
filings, capping rates is likely to increase minutes of use, thus
raising revenues, and this would likely make up for such imputed
reduction in revenue. The few remaining providers potentially could
face larger imputed reductions in revenue (assuming their reported
costs were efficient). However, these providers have reported costs
significantly higher than the industry average, even more strongly
suggesting that they are likely to be inefficient providers. In any
event, to the extent such providers can demonstrate that they are
unable to receive fair compensation under our rate caps, they would be
eligible to seek a waiver as described below.
66. In short, our revenue estimates are likely understatements, for
the reasons described below. We also find that many of the providers'
reported costs are likely to be higher than efficiently-incurred costs,
and this is specifically the case for the carriers just discussed.
Consequently, we have a high degree of confidence that our prescribed
caps would allow efficient providers of ICS to operate profitably.
67. Our revenue imputation likely underestimates the actual
revenues providers would obtain for four reasons. First, our analysis
does not take into account the demand stimulation from lower rates. But
there is substantial record evidence showing that, to the extent that
our caps lower existing rates, they will increase minutes of use and
raise provider revenues.
68. Second, we impute rates that in some cases will be lower than
the rates the providers may actually charge. The resulting revenue
underestimate could be material for six of the providers for which we
impute losses at our prescribed rate caps, meaning that as a practical
matter they could make up for any shortfall. All these providers have
jail contracts with ADPs of at least 350, and some of these providers
have a large number of such contracts. To estimate each provider's
revenues under the rate caps we adopt today, we calculate the revenues
the provider would have earned given the MOU the provider reported for
2012 and 2013 for debit and prepaid calls in the three different jail
size categories, 0-349, 350-999, and 1,000+, for prisons, and for
collect calls (so, for example, if a carrier had 1,000 debit MOU in the
0-349 category, we assume the provider would earn $220 (=
1,000*$0.22)). This approach can understate revenues because providers
reported contracts according to the sum of the ADP of the facilities
covered under the contract, but in some cases providers will charge
different rates in different facilities supplied under the same
contract. In that case, when the contract has an ADP of 350 or more,
but the provider serves under the contract jails with an ADP that is
lower than the contract ADP, our estimate will understate the revenues
they would have earned if our prescribed rates were applied. For
example, a contract with an ADP of between 350 and 999 that currently
sets different rates for different facilities might cover three jails,
each with an ADP of 150. In that case, while we would impute a rate of
$0.16 to the prepaid and debit MOU reported under that contract, in
reality the provider could be entitled to the $0.22 rate cap on all
those MOU. Similarly, all jails reported under contracts with an ADP of
1,000 or more were imputed the debit and prepaid rate of $0.14, but
some of these jails could have ADPs of less than 1,000, and in some
cases of less than 350. If the contract specified separate rates by
facility, then the provider could be entitled to either the $0.16 or
the $0.22 rate in those smaller jails.
69. Third, our analysis also does not take into account the caps
that we impose on ancillary service charges, which likely will lead to
an increase in minutes of use. Finally, our analysis does not take into
account the fact that international calls are not subject to our rate
caps and therefore, such calls will produce more revenue than
reflected.
70. A few providers, including GTL, Securus and Telmate, contend
that our rate caps are too low and will not allow them to recover their
costs. Others assert that our rate caps may be too low with respect to
particular facilities. Some representatives of jail facilities express
concern that the provision of ICS in
[[Page 79146]]
their facilities may be in jeopardy. Based on our analysis and the
record, we find these assertions unpersuasive. Several providers
dispute their claims, noting that GTL, Securus, and Telmate failed to
break out their costs by facility type, and proposed rate caps well
above their reported average costs over both prisons and jails. As a
result, ``any claim that the Commission's draft rates are demonstrably
below carriers' reported costs is wholly unsubstantiated and without
merit.'' Our analysis indicates that the rate caps we adopt will permit
just, reasonable, and fair compensation. Moreover, we expect that the
reforms adopted will lead to increased minutes of use, incentivize
increased efficiency, and permit providers to generate increased
revenues. Thus, we do not believe that there is a reason for service to
facilities to be in jeopardy but, as noted below, there is a process
for considering any unique circumstances that may justify a waiver to
ensure fair compensation.
c. Evidence That the Mandatory Data Collection Likely Overstates
Providers' Costs
71. In addition to the analysis detailed above, evidence in the
record suggesting that a number of ICS providers overstated their costs
in response to the Mandatory Data Collection provides us with further
comfort that the rate caps adopted today are appropriate and ensure
fair compensation to the providers.
72. For instance, providers were directed to file a Description and
Justification (D&J) with their Mandatory Data Collection response to
document and explain their cost submissions. Three providers did not
submit a D&J to the Commission. The D&Js received varied widely in
detail and thoroughness. Five providers (CenturyLink, GTL, Pay Tel,
Securus, and Telmate) claimed a cost of capital of 11.25 percent in
developing their cost data submission. (While other providers did not
specify a cost of capital, given the length of this proceeding and the
fact that the Commission clearly signaled its focus on setting
appropriate ICS rates, as well as the fact that these respondents are
sophisticated parties, we think that it is reasonable to assume that
all responding providers included a cost of capital whether they
specified it or not.) The cost of capital has to be estimated and their
estimate of 11.25 percent might be significantly higher than the
prevailing cost of capital for companies that provide telecommunication
services. In any event, none of these companies submitted evidence as
to their costs of debt or equity capital or capital structure, the
three components of the cost of capital, and so have not justified any
cost of capital estimate. In addition, several providers (Securus,
Telmate, and CenturyLink) included in their costs financing items as
well as interest expense, which is included in the cost of capital.
This suggests that these providers, and possibly others, have over-
estimated their capital costs, potentially double-counting their cost
of debt. The five providers that specifically reported using 11.25
percent account for a large portion of the market, and thus a
commensurate weight is reflected in the weighted average caps that we
calculate. Consequently, in the unlikely event that a provider omitted
its cost of capital, the omission is unlikely to have a significant
impact on the weighted average caps. We also note that the Bureau has
recommended to the Commission that a zone of reasonableness for the
Weighted Average Cost of Capital (WACC) is between 7.39 and 8.72
percent.
73. We also find that the manner in which the data was collected
and the clearly-stated purpose of the data collection, which occurred
in the context of a Commission effort to set caps on ICS rates, gave
providers every incentive to represent their ICS costs fully, and
possibly, in some instances, even to overstate these costs. For
example, one provider noted in its D&J that it even included in its
ICS-related costs amounts for dues, subscriptions, entertainment and
meals. We question the appropriateness of including such costs as ICS-
related costs but as noted below we accept these reported costs without
discounting or manipulating them. We have observed that at least one
reporting provider did not actually calculate the percentage of traffic
for each service (debit, prepaid or collect) represented but rather
used the same percentage for each and merely offered a ``guess'' in
reporting its 2014 data projections. This information forces us to call
into question the accuracy of this provider's data and how rigorous
this provider was in preparing its Mandatory Data Collection response.
That the adopted rate caps include such costs, as well as the costs of
international calls that are not subject to our rate caps, causes us to
conclude that the adopted caps are generous. An analysis of the adopted
rate caps shows that some providers will recover more than their stated
costs, while others will recover less (because the caps are based on
weighted industry averages but, as explained above, we believe all
providers can more than recover the efficient costs of ICS supply).
74. Moreover, comments in the record have also highlighted how the
data likely overstate costs. For example, the Petitioners' economist,
Coleman Bazelon, and Pay Tel's economic consultant Don Wood identified
problems they observed with the data. Dr. Bazelon also reported that,
based on an analysis that included information not included in the
provider's Mandatory Data Collection submissions, the reported costs of
Securus and GTL ``include many incorrectly calculated additions such as
inappropriately recoverable financing costs.'' Dr. Bazelon reports
that, [BEGIN CONFIDENTIAL] [END CONFIDENTIAL].
75. After recalculating the providers' costs, Dr. Bazelon then
concludes that their reported costs should be discounted by
approximately [BEGIN CONFIDENTIAL] [END CONFIDENTIAL]. While we do not
discount the costs as recommended by Dr. Bazelon and, instead, take a
more conservative approach of using the data at face value, this
analysis underscores that the data submitted likely overstates costs
and, as a result, the rate caps we adopt today are conservative.
d. Alternative Proposals in the Record
76. Numerous commenters have submitted rate reform proposals in the
record. The Petitioners, along with several public interest groups,
initially urged the Commission to adopt a $0.07 per minute rate cap for
all interstate debit, prepaid, and collect calls, with no per-call
charge, and no ancillary fees or taxes allowed. GTL, Securus, and
Telmate, who describe themselves as ``the primary providers of inmate
calling services . . . in the United States and represent[ ] 85% of the
industry revenue in 2013,'' jointly filed a proposal to comprehensively
reform all aspects of ICS. The Joint Provider Proposal urges the
adoption of rate caps of $0.20 per minute for debit and prepaid
interstate and intrastate ICS, and $0.24 per minute for all interstate
and intrastate collect ICS, effective 90 days after adoption of a final
order. The Joint Provider Proposal does not indicate that it is based
on cost data received in response to the Mandatory Data Collection. In
addition, the Joint Provider Proposal was signed by only three of the
14 ICS providers that responded to the Mandatory Data Collection. Pay
Tel submitted what it calls an ``Ethical Proposal,'' in which it
proposes rate caps of $0.08 per minute for all prisons regardless of
population, $0.26 per minute for jails with 1-349 ADP, and
[[Page 79147]]
$0.22 per minute for jails with 350 plus ADP. The Commission sought
comment on these proposals in the Second FNPRM.
77. In response to the Second FNPRM, Petitioners submitted another
reform proposal. The Petitioners propose a rate of $0.08/minute for
prepaid and debit calls and $0.10/minute for collect calls from all
prisons and jails with over 350 beds. Petitioners propose a rate of
$0.18/minute for prepaid and debit calls and $0.20/minute for collect
for facilities with fewer than 350 beds. Petitioners suggest that the
Commission adopt these tiered rates to account for higher churn rates,
increased non-revenue calls, and higher bad debt issues experienced in
smaller facilities. In its comments to the Second FNPRM, PPI supports a
cap of $0.05 to $0.07 per minute.
78. Several commenters submitted economic justifications for their
rate proposals, each of which relied on a slightly different subset of
the data in the Mandatory Data Collection. For the reasons described
below, the Commission declines to adopt any of these proposals.
79. After comments were received in response to the Second FNPRM,
Pay Tel filed an additional proposal based on its economic consultant's
analysis of the data filed in response to the Mandatory Data
Collection. The company proposes tiered per-minute rate caps, for all
call types, plus institution cost recovery amounts to be added to those
caps. The rates (rate cap plus additional facility cost recovery) would
range from $0.10/min for prisons to $0.29/min for jails of 0-349
inmates. Specifically, Pay Tel's economic consultant, Don Wood,
excluded from his analysis, and subsequent proposed rate caps, the data
from ATN, Encartele, and Protocall because he did not receive data from
those providers, and from Combined Public Communications, Custom
Teleconnect and Correct Solutions, because he deemed them ``unreliable
for the purpose at hand.'' Mr. Wood then observed that the remaining
eight reporting ICS providers' data included no description of how
their cost studies were performed, and stated that ``a number of the
studies are decidedly imperfect, and more complete documentation would
certainly be desirable.'' Regardless, Mr. Wood suggested that ``key
results of these studies should be relied upon by the Commission when
making any decisions regarding the level and structure of ICS costs.''
We conclude that our approach is more appropriate because it includes
data from all providers, rather than excluding six of the fourteen
reporting providers' data. This approach is less reliable than our rate
caps because of its selective nature. While we agree that the data are
not perfect, we do not believe it is appropriate to ignore the filed
data and we find Mr. Wood's rationale for excluding certain providers'
data unpersuasive without additional justification. As such, the rate
caps adopted herein are derived from all data filed in the record.
80. In comments to the Second FNPRM, the Wright Petitioners'
economist, Coleman Bazelon, identified problems he observed with the
data received in response to the Mandatory Data Collection. For
example, Dr. Bazelon identified inconsistencies in how providers
categorized and allocated costs. Dr. Bazelon then discussed the rate
caps that the Wright Petitioners' proposed in their comments. These
rate caps were based on Securus' and GTL's average cost data, which Dr.
Bazelon then discounted because of concerns regarding Securus' cost-
reporting methodology. As noted above, Dr. Bazelon found errors in
Securus' and GTL's submissions, which led them to likely overstate
their reported costs. After adjusting for these errors, the Wright
Petitioners suggest that an appropriate rate cap for service to prison
facilities should be $0.08/minute for debit/prepaid calling and $0.10/
minute for collect calling.
81. We appreciate Dr. Bazelon's analysis highlighting that the data
are likely to be overstated, but we do not believe it is appropriate
for our purposes. Dr. Bazelon's analysis suggests that one provider may
have overstated its costs by some significant amount. We find Dr.
Bazelon's analysis of the submitted data troubling and believe that his
conclusions, if true, might support discounting cost data from certain
providers. (We note, however, that our filing instructions did not
specify in detail how providers should account for the data that Dr.
Bazelon discussed, although we required providers to identify and
explain all costs in the accompanying Description and Justification.
The lack of specific instruction regarding the method of cost reporting
should not have been interpreted as license to manipulate or over-
report cost data, and the reference to the penalty for willful false
statements should have made that evident.) While we are concerned that
the analysis from Dr. Bazelon suggests that costs were overstated, we
do not believe it is appropriate to adopt a rate cap based on
discounting a single provider's costs when we have data from 13 other
providers. In addition, we determine above that we should not
manipulate the data but more conservatively accept the providers' costs
as filed to avoid potentially arbitrary means of working with the data.
82. Alabama Public Service Commission Utility Services Division
Director Darrell Baker likewise reviewed the data. His proposal
includes four tiers each for prisons and jails, based on inmate
population, with both rate caps and additional facility cost-recovery
amounts, yielding rates ranging from $0.12/min (prisons with more than
19,999 inmates) to $0.25/min (jails of less than 100 inmates). In
support of his proposal for prison rates, Mr. Baker relied on cost data
from only seven of the reporting 14 providers. He excluded from his
rate cap and cost-recovery calculations the seven smallest reporting
providers, on the basis ``that the . . . [remaining] providers serve
the overwhelming majority of jails and prisons and that . . . an
analysis of their data should provide accurate and reliable results
that are applicable across the entire industry.'' In support of his
proposal for jail rates, Mr. Baker relied on data from only six of the
reporting providers, excluding one of the seven remaining providers'
data because that ``[o]ne provider's cost per MOU deviates
substantially from the cost per MOU of other providers.'' We find Mr.
Baker's approach problematic because it eliminated the higher cost data
in the record. Put another way, the seven smallest providers submitted
what were among the highest reported costs of providing ICS and the
other excluded provider by process of elimination must be a larger
provider that is responsible for a more-significant portion of ICS
minutes of use. Additionally, Mr. Baker appears to have given no
consideration to potential justifications, if any, for that provider's
higher costs. We are unable, on the record before us, to exclude
providers' reported data in calculating the appropriate rate caps.
83. The comments in the record largely agree that the data are
problematic but disagree on the reasons why and the overall effect on
the reported data. Each analysis described above is based on a
different data set and criticizes the data for slightly different
reasons. We take seriously the concerns that the commenters have raised
about inconsistencies in the data, and for at least some of the reasons
described above, conclude that the reported data likely overstates the
providers' actual costs. But, as explained herein, we are unable to
agree with and do not adopt any of the commenters' choices about which
data to exclude or discount.
[[Page 79148]]
e. Rate Caps for Collect Calls
84. In this section, we conclude that it is appropriate to put in
place a temporary, distinct rate structure for collect calls, with a
two-year phase down after which rate caps for collect calls will be the
same as those of debit and prepaid calls.
85. In the 2013 Order, the Commission established a rate cap for
interstate debit and prepaid calling and a separate rate cap for
interstate collect calling. The interim interstate collect calling rate
cap was $0.25. In setting this separate rate cap, the Commission
recognized that, based on the data available at the time, collect
calling can be more expensive for ICS providers to offer than debit and
prepaid calling. The Commission encouraged facilities to move away from
collect calling, noting that the use of prepaid calling helps called
parties to better manage their budgets for ICS, thus making end-user
costs for maintaining contact more predictable. The Commission also
noted that debit and prepaid calling address the problem of call
blocking associated with collect calling by enabling service providers
to obtain payment for calls up front, thus eliminating the risk of
nonpayment.
86. In the Second FNPRM, the Commission sought comment on retaining
the differentials between debit/prepaid and collect calling. The
Commission noted that data received from the Mandatory Data Collection
suggest that collect calling costs are higher than costs for prepaid
and debit calls, and that collect calling accounted for less than nine
percent of revenue producing minutes in the data collection in 2013.
Commenters suggest that collect calling is more costly to provide
because of bad debt, billing costs, uncollectible debts and issues
related to collection of non-payment. For example, some commenters
still assert that the Commission should adopt a higher rate cap for
collect calling, largely because of the higher costs associated with
collect call service. The Commission, along with several commenters,
has noted that use of collect calling in correctional facilities has
dropped significantly in recent years. Data received in response to the
Mandatory Data Collection confirm this decline. Between 2012 and 2014,
collect-calling minutes of use decreased over 50 percent, from 15 to 7
percent of minutes of use. CenturyLink recently told the Commission
that ``that traditional collect calling represents a small and
declining percentage of inmate calls.''
87. Based on our analysis of the record, including data submitted
in response to the Mandatory Data Collection, we predict that collect
calling usage will continue to decrease in the future. We do not want
to include high collect calling costs in debit and prepaid rate tiers
because that would compel the majority of ICS end users that do not use
collect calling to subsidize such calls. In light of that concern, and
because we continue to encourage correctional institutions to move away
from collect calling, as the Commission did in the 2013 Order, we adopt
a separate rate cap tier for collect calling. This separate tier is
consistent with the Commission's prior actions in adopting a separate
collect calling rate tier based on data indicating that collect calls
were more expensive than other types of ICS calls. Since the adoption
of our interim rate caps, only one provider has been granted a waiver
based on an assertion of unreasonable or unsustainable rate caps,
further supporting the reasonableness of the rate of the interim
collect calling rate caps.
88. We adopt a collect calling rate cap based on the cost data
received in response to the Mandatory Data Collection, as well as a
two-year step-down transitional period, as follows. First, we adopt a
collect calling rate of $0.49/per minute for all jails and $0.14 for
all prisons until July 1, 2017. Beginning July 1, 2017, we adopt a rate
of $0.36/per minute for jails of 0-349 ADP, $0.33/per minute for jails
of 349-999 ADP, and $0.32/per minute for jails of 1,000 or greater ADP,
and $0.14/per minute for all prisons. This rate is halfway between the
initial rate and the rates that are adopted in this Order for debit and
prepaid calling. Finally, effective July 1, 2018 and beyond, we adopt a
collect calling rate of $0.22/per minute for jails of 0-349 ADP, $0.16/
per minute for jails with 359-999 ADP, and $0.14/per minute for jails
of 1,000 or greater ADP, and $0.11/per minute for all prisons, in order
to arrive at rates that are identical to those adopted in this Order
for jails and prisons and the respective tiers therein.
89. We conclude that these separate tiers for collect calling rates
will phase out after a two-year transition period. This two-year
framework is justified by the data filed in response to the Mandatory
Data Collection, showing that collect calling volume is decreasing and
will most likely be at a nominal level in two years. By adopting a two-
year glide path, the rates ICS providers are permitted to charge phase
down over time, with certainty and sufficient time to adapt to a
changed landscape that includes reduced use of collect calling overall.
We find that this transitional approach will be administratively
efficient for both providers and the Commission, as it involves a
straightforward two-year step-down process and reflects our expectation
that providers will gain efficiencies in their contracts and collect
calling, and that they will thus more easily adjust to the lower rate
caps adopted for debit and prepaid calling.
90. Moreover, the record supports a uniform rate for collect calls.
Indeed, several commenters no longer support a separate rate cap for
collect calling, indicating that collect calling costs may not, in
fact, differ significantly from debit or prepaid calling costs, or that
collect calling accounts for a relatively small portion of calls. The
record indicates that this is because correctional institutions favor
debit or prepaid calling over collect calling. For example, when the
Commission adopted the 2013 Order, evidence in the record indicated
that collect calling was the only ICS option offered in four states and
now the record indicates that collect calling is the only ICS option in
one state. As the Commission has stated previously, we encourage
providers and facilities to move away from collect calling for the many
efficiencies and cost savings that other types of calling offer.
Finally, we find that a two-year transition will allow the Bureau to
monitor collect calling and address any potential traffic arbitrage
issue that might occur if providers shift calling patterns to take
advantage of the higher collect calling rate caps.
91. We acknowledge that the collect calling rate caps will be
higher in year one than several of the collect calling caps proposed in
the record. We expect that these caps will serve as backstops, not a
target for providers, as efficiencies are gained by providers, and
contracts are changed, or new contracts are entered into between
parties. As discussed above, we expect that the trend towards declining
collect calling volume will continue, and the adopted rate caps may be
further modified in response to further data received as part of the
MDC adopted herein.
92. We delegate to the Bureau the authority to seek comment on the
possibility of adjusting the adopted collect calling rate cap if
necessary to address any gaming issues that may arise prior to
completion of the phase-down. As part of the annual reporting and
certification requirement adopted herein, the Bureau will be monitoring
collect call volume in order to review trends and to ensure that gaming
does not occur. As discussed below, the
[[Page 79149]]
Commission also plans to collect rate data, including data about
collect calling rates that will further inform this review.
f. Cost-Benefit Analysis
93. In adopting these rate caps, we have carefully considered each
proposal or suggestion from the extensive comments in the record and
weighed its potential benefit against any potential burden it may
impose, bearing in mind our statutory mandate that ICS rates must be
just, reasonable, and fair, maximizing the public benefit from any
proposal we adopt. We find, on balance, that the benefits of our rate
caps outweigh any potential burden that may be imposed. For example,
regular family contact not only benefits the public broadly by reducing
crime, lessening the need for additional correctional facilities and
cutting overall costs to society, but also likely has a positive effect
on the welfare of inmates' children. Ensuring just and reasonable ICS
rates will foster regular contact between inmates and families, reduce
the economic burden on ICS end users, support more cost-effective
communication between inmates and their counsel, and produce cost
savings for the justice system.
94. Additionally, as the Commission discussed in the 2012 NPRM,
studies show that regular contact with family reduces inmate
recidivism. Children who continue to stay in touch with their parent in
prison exhibit fewer disruptive and anxious behaviors. Yet, according
to one study, only 38 percent of inmates reported ``at least'' monthly
phone calls with their children. Real telephone contact between inmates
and their loved ones at high rates places a heavy burden on inmates'
families because families typically bear the burden of paying for the
calls. The Government Accountability Office (GAO) has twice recognized
the conclusions of Federal Bureau of Prisons officials that contact
with family ``aids an inmate's success when returning to the
community'' and thus lowers recidivism. Moreover, the GAO has found
that ``crowded visiting rooms make it more difficult for inmates to
visit with their families'' and that ``[t]he infrastructure of the
facility may not support the increase in visitors as a result of the
growth in the prison population.''
95. As discussed above, there is little dispute that the ICS market
is experiencing market failure. Numerous commenters have expressed as
much. Various parties encourage the Commission to reform rates within
inmate calling, and some offer specific reform proposals. Reforms are
necessary to ensure that the benefits discussed above, which are in the
public interest, will be realized.
96. The Order recognizes, however, that imposing rate caps may
impose burdens on some providers. We have taken steps to minimize
burdens on providers. As discussed below, we allow a 90-day transition
period for the rate caps adopted in this Order to take effect for
prisons and six months for the applicable rate caps to take effect in
jails. We find that this length of time adequately balances the
pressing need for reform while affording ICS providers and facilities
sufficient time to prepare for the new rates. Further, our rate caps
are designed to ensure that efficient providers will recover all
legitimate costs of providing ICS, including a reasonable return, and,
to the extent a provider can demonstrate special circumstances, it may
seek relief from our rules in the form of a waiver. Specifically, the
Commission will consider requests from a provider arguing that
particular facts, when considered in the context of the totality of the
relevant circumstances, deprive the provider of fair compensation or
have a substantial and deleterious effect on competition in the ICS
market.
97. Additionally, the rate caps adopted in the Order include fewer
tiers than the number of tiers used in the data requested in our
Mandatory Data Collection. The Commission collected data, for example,
on the costs of serving jail facilities with 0-99 ADP, a grouping
comprising less than 10 percent of the inmate population, but we did
not adopt that as a rate tier, thereby mitigating any administrative
burden on providers of adding a separate rate tier for this
comparatively small grouping. The rate caps we adopt today respond to
commenter concerns regarding potential confusion and burden caused by
multiple rates. We also adopt a single rate cap for prisons, which
should minimize the burden on providers that serve prisons. Finally, we
disagree with those commenters who assert that adopting a tiered rate
structure would be unduly burdensome and difficult for the Commission
to administer and for ICS providers and correctional officers to
implement. We find these allegations unsupported and commenters provide
no persuasive evidence that our rate tiers would be more difficult for
them to administer than the current approaches.
4. Rejection of Certain Types of Charges
a. No Per-Call or Per-Connection Charges
98. Background. Per-call or per-connection charges are one-time
fees often charged to ICS users at call initiation. In the 2013 Order,
the Commission noted problems with per-call charges, ``potentially
rendering such charges unjust, unreasonable and unfair.'' Problems
included calls dropped ``without regard to whether there is a potential
security or technical issue, and a per-call charge . . . imposed on the
initial call and each successive call.'' The Commission expressed
``serious concerns about such charges'' and sought comment about the
risks of such charges, but did not ban them.
99. In the Second FNPRM, the Commission sought additional comment
about such charges. First, the Commission asked if it should consider
per-call or per-connection charges to be part of the ICS rate and
``therefore subject to the section 276 mandate to ensure fair
compensation.'' Second, the Commission asked, in the alternative, if it
should consider per-call or per-connection fees more analogous to the
ancillary fees discussed in section 276(d). The Commission asked if
there are ``instances in which the correctional facility or some other
third party assesses a per-call or per-connection fee,'' and, if so,
the Commission sought comment on its authority to ban such charges.
Finally, the Commission sought comment on whether the elimination of
per-call charges would allow for just and reasonable interstate and
intrastate ICS rates and fair compensation for ICS providers, on
``transitions'' away from such charges, and on its legal authority to
act on per-call or per-connection charges.
100. We received limited comment in the record, but all supported
the elimination of per-call or per-connection fees. For example, HRDC
supports the ``elimination of per-call charges'' for existing
contracts. Legal Services for Prisoners with Children asserts that
``per-call'' or connection fees are ``unreasonably high'' and that the
Commission ``should ban these charges'' or, ``at the very least,''
should introduce a ``dropped call'' provision that ``prohibits ICS
providers from charging multiple times for a call that has been
reinitiated within a few minutes.'' Pay Tel notes that if the
Commission adopts ``any rate cap regime--including Pay Tel's Proposal--
that does not allow providers to charge end users an upfront surcharge
or per-call surcharge, it will
[[Page 79150]]
successfully eliminate the problem of premature disconnection of
calls.''
101. Discussion. We disallow the use of per-call or per-connection
charges pursuant to our legal authority to ensure just, reasonable, and
fair ICS rates. No evidence in the record supports a conclusion that
these charges are a necessary part of cost recovery for ICS calls.
Indeed, no commenters indicated that these fees are tied to a cost that
providers incur in initiating a call. Providers did not break out per-
call or per-connection costs when they filed their per-minute costs in
response to the Mandatory Data Collection, indicating that any costs
incurred on a per-call basis were included in their per-minute cost
calculations. Allowing providers to recover such charges on top of the
per-minute rates we adopt in this Order would therefore risk allowing
double recovery. Additionally, these fees appear to be less prevalent
than they once were. Recent provider-drafted reform proposals in the
record do not include per-call or per-connection charges, and many
recently-adopted ICS contracts likewise do not include these fees. All
of these factors indicate to us a trend away from the inclusion of such
fees. Finally, we agree with the Commission's earlier finding in the
2013 Order that allowing such fees may encourage providers to charge
end users for dropped calls, which could lead to the ``assessment of
multiple per-call charges for what was, in effect, a single
conversation,'' which has no place in a framework for just, reasonable,
and fair compensation. We find that disallowing such fees is in the
public interest because it will decrease the cost to end users for
shorter ICS calls and allow more contact between inmates and their
loved ones.
b. No Flat-Rate Calling
102. Background. In the 2013 Order the Commission noted that
commenters raised issues regarding per-call charges that may be unjust,
unreasonable, and unfair; callers are often charged more during a
single conversation when calls are dropped, which the record reveals
can be a frequent occurrence, thus resulting in multiple calls for a
single conversation, each subject to a separate flat-rate charge. The
Commission stated that ``a rate will be considered consistent with our
rate cap for a 15-minute conversation if it does not exceed $3.75 for a
15-minute call using collect calling, or $3.15 for a 15-minute call
using debit, prepaid, or prepaid collect calling.'' Rule 64.6030
mirrors this language and was intended to illustrate that the rate for
a five-minute collect call must be capped at $1.25 and the rate for a
five-minute debit or prepaid ICS call must be capped at $1.05, while a
30-minute collect call could cost consumers no more than $7.50 and a
30-minute debit or prepaid ICS call no more than $6.30.
103. Discussion. Subsequent to the 2013 Order, Securus sought
additional guidance on this issue, asking whether providers were
allowed to impose a flat rate based on the interim rate caps for a 15-
minute call regardless of actual call duration. That is, it wished to
know if it could charge a flat fee of $3.75 for a collect call of any
duration up to 15 minutes. The Commission sought comment on Securus'
question, as well as on whether it should revise the existing rules to
prohibit flat-rate charges or to develop new rules prohibiting flat-
rated charges.
104. The record reflects minimal support for this practice. The
Alabama PSC opposes Securus' proposed clarification, stating that
``flat-rate pricing allows providers to maximize call revenues and to
dictate phone usage to the end users.'' It further asserts that flat-
rate calling increases complaints related to dropped calls and
penalizes inmates that want to make shorter calls. Several commenters
suggest that ICS providers will benefit from a ban on flat-rate calls
because it will lower their costs related to consumer complaints and
bill adjustments. HRDC notes that the proposed flat rates ``only fall
within the rate caps when a full 15-minute call is actually completed''
and argues that ``this practice does not reflect the spirit'' of the
Commission's 2013 Order. Pay Tel asserts that ``numerous ICS providers
have taken advantage of this language and vague guidance since release
of the ICS Order and are charging end users a flat rate of $3.15 or
$3.75 per call, even if the call is disconnected prior to expiration of
fifteen minutes,'' which it asserts is ``an abuse of the intent of the
Commission's rules.''
105. We prohibit the imposition of flat-rate calling. There is
minimal record support for such charges, which penalize those who make
shorter calls (the record indicates that ICS calls last typically less
than 15 minutes). If an end user is charged for a 15-minute call but
the duration of that call is less than 15 minutes, the price for that
call is disproportionately high. We also agree with those commenters
who assert that allowing providers to charge a flat rate based on a 15-
minute call does not comport with our requirement to make ICS rates
just, reasonable, and fair. As such, we ban flat-rate calling rate
plans.
5. Legal Authority for Intrastate and Interstate Rate Caps
106. Background. In the 2013 FNPRM, the Commission tentatively
concluded that section 276 affords it broad authority to reform
intrastate ICS rates and practices that deny fair compensation, as well
as to preempt inconsistent state requirements. The Commission sought
comment on these tentative conclusions. Multiple commenters supported
the Commission's tentative conclusion that it has jurisdiction over
intrastate as well as interstate ICS rates. These commenters argue that
section 276 provides the Commission with clear jurisdiction, and that
it must regulate intrastate rates to ensure comprehensive ICS reform.
After examining the record, we affirm the tentative conclusion that
intrastate ICS rates are well within the Commission's jurisdiction for
the reasons described below.
107. Our authority to ensure the reasonableness of rates and
practices for interstate ICS is not in dispute. Under section 201(b) of
the Communications Act, the FCC is empowered to ``prescribe such rules
and regulations as may be necessary'' to ensure that ``[a]ll charges
[and] practices . . . for and in connection with [interstate]
communication service'' by wire or radio are ``just and reasonable.''
Section 276 directs the Commission to ``establish a per call
compensation plan to ensure that all payphone service providers''--
which the statute defines to include providers of ICS--``are fairly
compensated for each and every completed intrastate and interstate
call.'' (The Commission has previously found that the term ``fairly
compensated'' permits a range of compensation rates that could be
considered fair, but that the interests of both the payphone service
providers and the parties paying the compensation must be taken into
account.) We find that these statutory sections provide the Commission
with the authority to regulate interstate ICS rates and practices,
including the use of per-call or per-connection fees as well as flat-
rate calling.
108. Legal Authority to Reform Intrastate Rates. The Commission's
authority over intrastate telecommunications is, except as otherwise
provided by Congress, generally limited by section 2(b) of the Act,
which states that ``nothing in this Act shall . . . give the Commission
jurisdiction with respect to . . . intrastate communication service by
wire or radio.'' As the Supreme Court has held, however, section 2(b)
has no
[[Page 79151]]
effect where the Communications Act, by its terms, unambiguously
applies to intrastate services. We conclude that such is the case here.
109. Under section 276 of the Communications Act, the Commission is
charged with implementing Congress's directive ``that all payphone
service providers [be] fairly compensated for each and every completed
intrastate and interstate call.'' Section 276 contains several express
references both to ICS and intrastate calling, making it clear that the
Commission has the authority to regulate intrastate ICS calling. For
example, section 276 requires the Commission to broadly craft
regulations to ``promote the widespread development of payphone
services for the benefit of the general public'' including, notably,
``the provision of inmate telephone service in correctional
institutions, and any ancillary services.'' In addition to this general
grant of jurisdiction, section 276 includes a mandate to ``establish a
per call compensation plan to ensure that all payphone service
providers are fairly compensated for each and every completed
intrastate and interstate call using their payphone.'' Section 276 also
expressly directs the Commission to ``discontinue the intrastate and
interstate carrier access charge payphone service elements. . .and all
intrastate and interstate payphone subsidies.'' In addition, section
276 explicitly grants the Commission authority to preempt state
requirements to the extent they are inconsistent with FCC regulations.
110. Furthermore, significant judicial precedent supports the
Commission's authority to regulate intrastate ICS. In Illinois Public
Telecommunications Association, the U.S. Court of Appeals for the D.C.
Circuit found that the Act's requirement that ``all payphone service
providers are fairly compensated'' provides the FCC with ``authority to
set local coin call rates''--which included intrastate service rates.
Additionally, in New England Public Comm'ns Council, Inc. v. FCC, the
same court found that ``section 276 unambiguously and straightforwardly
authorizes the Commission to regulate . . . intrastate payphone line
rates.'' Therefore, we conclude that both section 276 and the
associated case law give the Commission the authority to regulate ICS
provider compensation for intrastate calls, including the rates ICS
providers charge end users, per-call or per-connection charges, and
flat-rate charges.
111. We find arguments that the Commission lacks the authority to
regulate intrastate ICS unpersuasive. For example, we disagree with
commenters who argue that section 276 is limited to prohibiting
discrimination by Bell operating companies (BOCs). While section 276(a)
includes provisions specifically prohibiting discrimination by BOCs, we
do not believe Congress intended for that subsection to limit the scope
of the remaining provisions of section 276. For example, section
276(b)(1) expressly mandates that the Commission adopt regulations
addressing five specific subjects related to payphone services; only
two of those subjects--clauses (C) and (D)--relate to preventing BOC
discrimination.
112. In addition, although section 276(a) refers to Bell operating
companies, and applies only to the BOCs, section 276(b) refers more
broadly to ``payphone service providers.'' If Congress had intended for
the regulations prescribed under section 276(b) to be limited to the
narrow purpose of effectuating the nondiscrimination goals set forth in
section 276(a), it easily could have made that clear. Instead, Congress
made clear that it was conferring a broader mandate in section 276(b),
stating that: ``[i]n order to promote competition among payphone
service providers and to promote the widespread deployment of payphone
services . . . , the Commission shall take all actions necessary . . .
to prescribe regulations that . . . [inter alia] ensure that all
payphone service providers are fairly compensated for each and every
completed intrastate and interstate call using their payphone[s] . . .
.''
113. We also disagree with commenters who argue that the Commission
has never determined that section 276 extends to intrastate rates or
that section 276 applies only to ``local calls made from a payphone and
paid with coins.'' Section 276 does not specify that compensation is
only for calls paid by coin but rather ``each and every'' call. Indeed,
the very Commission order under review in Illinois Public
Telecommunications held that the Commission had the authority to
regulate intrastate payphone rates and preempt state regulation of
intrastate rates. Therefore, the Commission's position regarding its
authority over intrastate rates under section 276 has remained
consistent.
114. Rate Caps are Just, Reasonable and Fair. As noted above, we
have accepted the data submitted by providers in response to the
Mandatory Data Collection as reported even though there is evidence
that they are overstated. As a result, we believe our rate caps are
conservative and include sufficiently generous margins to allow
providers to earn a profit. More generally, it is well-established that
rates can be lawful if they fall within a zone of reasonableness, and
hence a particular state's cap might be lower than our caps and still
fall within that zone. The rate caps we adopt today are intended both
to ensure that ICS rates are ``just and reasonable'' and do not take
unfair advantage of inmates, their families, or providers consistent
with the ``fair compensation'' mandate of section 276.
115. The Commission has broad discretion in establishing just and
reasonable rates, as long as it articulates a rational basis for its
decisions and as long as the result is not confiscatory. As the Supreme
Court has explained in construing the similar ``just and reasonable
rates'' provision of the Natural Gas Act, ``the Commission is not
required by the Constitution or the Natural Gas Act to adopt as just
and reasonable any particular rate level; rather, courts are without
authority to set aside any rate selected by the Commission which is
within a `zone of reasonableness.''' Section 276(b) charges us with
ensuring that ``all payphone service providers [be] fairly
compensated.'' This provision must be read in conjunction with our
obligation under section 201(b) to ensure that charges and practices be
just and reasonable. Neither section 276(b) nor 201(b) require us to
allow for recovery of costs that are not just, reasonable and fair.
116. We recognize that some ICS providers may see their profits
decrease because the adopted caps are below the costs they reported to
us under the Mandatory Data Collection (assuming that MOU stay
constant). The Commission has broad authority to set rate caps to apply
to a particular service and does not have to set provider-specific
rates that embody a rate of return for each individual provider.
Indeed, as at least one provider has explained in this proceeding,
courts have recognized that the use of industry-wide average cost data
to set rates is not arbitrary, and therefore agencies may use composite
industry data or other averaging methods to set rates. We therefore
find that the rates we adopt today are reasonable for the reasons
provided above and will allow economically efficient--possibly all--
providers to recover their costs that are reasonably and directly
attributable to ICS. The costs reported by the providers that are above
our rate caps represent significant outliers, suggesting that their
reporting methods may have varied from those of other providers or that
[[Page 79152]]
they may be less efficient than their peers. Indeed, encouraging
efficiency will lead to lower rates, which will both benefit end users
as well as increase calling demand, thus furthering the dual goals of
section 276 ``to promote competition among payphone service providers''
and encourage the ``widespread deployment of payphone services to the
benefit of the public.''
B. Payments to Correctional Institutions
117. The record indicates that, in many cases, ICS bids are
predicated on the winning providers' willingness to share part of its
ICS revenues with the correctional facility. These payments, commonly
referred to as ``site commissions,'' may take the form of monetary
payments, in-kind payments, exchanges, or allowances. In this Order, we
define the term ``site commission'' broadly, to encompass any form of
monetary payment, in-kind payment requirement, gift, exchange of
services or goods, fee, technology allowance, product or the like.
118. After carefully considering the evidence in the record, we
affirm our previous finding that site commissions do not constitute a
legitimate cost to the providers of providing ICS. Accordingly, we do
not include site commission payments in the cost data we use in setting
the rate caps established in this Order. We conclude that we do not
need to prohibit site commissions in order to ensure that interstate
rates for ICS are fair, just, and reasonable and that intrastate rates
are fair. We reiterate, however, that site commissions have been a
significant driver of rates and that ICS rates have dropped
dramatically in states that have eliminated site commissions. We
therefore encourage other states and correctional facilities to curtail
or prohibit such payments as part of an effort to further ensure that
inmates and their families have access to ICS at affordable rates.
119. We recognize that some states have adopted reasonable rates
that include a margin sufficient to allow providers to pay site
commissions, thus demonstrating that it is possible to have rates that
are consistent with our rate caps but still allow for the payment of
site commissions. The decision to establish fair and reasonable rate
caps for ICS and leave providers to decide whether to pay site
commissions--and if so, how much to pay--is supported by a broad cross-
section of commenters, including consumer advocates, such as the Wright
Petitioners; ICS providers, such as CenturyLink, NCIC and ICSolutions;
representatives of correctional facilities, such as Praeses; and state
regulators, such as the Alabama PSC. This broad support from
practically every type of interested party underscores the
reasonableness of our approach. We will continue to monitor the market
and will take appropriate action if we find that, notwithstanding our
rate caps, site commissions are somehow driving ICS rates to levels
that are unjust, unreasonable, or unfair.
1. Background
120. In the 2002 Order, the Commission concluded that, consistent
with prior precedent, site commissions ICS providers paid to inmate
facilities were not a cost of providing payphone service, ``but
represent an apportionment of profits between the facility owners and
the providers of [ICS].'' In the 2012 NPRM, the Commission sought
comment on its longstanding conclusion that site commissions are not a
cost of providing ICS, and additional comment and data on site
commissions and their impact on ICS rates.
121. In the subsequent 2013 Order, the Commission affirmed the
previous determination that site commissions ``are not costs that are
reasonably and directly related to the provision of ICS'' and
determined that site commissions were ``a significant factor
contributing to high [ICS] rates.'' The Commission concluded that,
``under the Act, [site] commission payments are not costs that can be
recovered through interstate ICS rates.'' The Commission noted,
however, the possibility that correctional facilities may incur costs
in making ICS available to inmates and sought comment on whether there
were any such costs that should be compensable through ICS rates.
122. In the Second FNPRM, the Commission sought additional comment
on potential reforms to site commissions and its legal authority to
``restrict the payment of site commissions in the ICS context pursuant
to sections 276 and 201(b) of the Act.'' As the Commission explained,
site commissions ``distort[] the ICS marketplace'' by creating
incentives for the facilities to select providers that pay the highest
site commissions, even if those providers do not offer the best service
or lowest rates. The Commission cited responses to the Mandatory Data
Collection showing that ICS providers paid over $460 million in site
commissions in 2013 alone. Press reports have cited even higher
figures. These payments represent a significant portion of total ICS
revenues. Indeed, as the Commission has noted, site commissions can
amount to as much as 96 percent of gross ICS revenues. The Commission,
therefore, sought comment on whether it should prohibit all site
commission payments for interstate and intrastate ICS. The Commission
also sought comment on whether correctional institutions incur any
costs in the provision of ICS, and requested data demonstrating that
any costs that facilities bear are ``directly related to the provision
of ICS.'' To the extent that correctional facilities were found to
incur costs ``reasonably and directly related to making ICS
available,'' the Commission sought comment on whether recovery of those
costs should be ``built into any per-minute ICS rate caps.''
2. Discussion
123. Although we do not prohibit providers from paying site
commissions, we do not consider the cost of any such payments in
setting our rate caps. (Regardless of whether site commission payments
constitute an ``appointment of profits'' or a cost to the provider,
they cannot be recovered through ICS rates unless they are ``reasonably
and directly related to the provision of ICS.) Evidence submitted in
response to the Second FNPRM reinforces the Commission's conclusion
that the site commissions ICS providers pay to some correctional
facilities are not reasonably related to the provision of ICS and
should not be considered in determining fair compensation for ICS
calls. HRDC, for example, describes site commissions as ``legal bribes
to induce correctional agencies to provide ICS providers with lucrative
monopoly contracts.'' Other parties use less colorful language, but
still indicate that site commissions often ``have nothing to do with
the provision'' of ICS. We agree with commenters opposed to recovery of
site commissions in ICS rates and find that site commission payments
should not be included in our rate cap calculations.
124. We therefore agree with inmate advocates, such as the Wright
Petitioners and the Civil Rights Coalition, a group of 20 national
civil rights and social justice organizations; providers, such as
CenturyLink and NCIC; United States Senators; and state regulators,
such as the Alabama PSC that, at this time, we should focus on our core
ratemaking authority in reforming ICS and not prohibit or specifically
regulate site commission payments. While we continue to view such
payments as an apportionment of profit, and therefore irrelevant to the
costs we consider in setting rate caps for ICS, we do not prohibit ICS
providers from paying site commissions. (Of course, providers' rates
must comply
[[Page 79153]]
with our rate caps, regardless of whether the provider pays site
commissions.)
125. The record supports excluding site commission payments from
the costs used to calculate the rate caps for ICS. Indeed, even many of
the commenters that oppose a prohibition on site commissions urge the
Commission to consider only costs related to the provision of ICS in
calculating the rate caps. If site commissions were factored into the
costs we used to set the rate caps, the caps would be significantly
higher. Passing the non-ICS-related costs that comprise site commission
payments including contributions to general revenue funds, onto inmates
and their families as part of the costs used to set rate caps would
result in rates that exceed the fair compensation required by section
276 and that are not just and reasonable, as required by section 201.
126. We note that several commenters argue that the programs
currently supported by site commissions should be paid for out of tax
funds collected from the population at large, or from other sources.
HRDC, for example, argues that ``all taxpayers should fund the cost of
operating correctional facilities, including the cost of providing
ICS,'' just as homeowners pay taxes to fund schools, regardless of
whether they have school-age children. We need not reach such arguments
to support our decision. Rather, we conclude that, because the programs
in question are unrelated to the provision or use of ICS, the burden of
paying for them may not, under the Communications Act, be imposed on
end users of ICS. As the Commission has explained, how facilities use
the site commission payments they receive from ICS providers is
irrelevant to our analysis: ``[t]he Act does not provide a mechanism
for funding social welfare programs or other costs unrelated to the
provision of ICS, no matter how successful or worthy.'' Consistent with
the record in this proceeding, as well as the Commission's decision in
the 2013 Order, we therefore exclude site commission payments from our
rate cap calculations.
127. In the Second FNPRM, the Commission sought comment on whether
it could or should prohibit site commissions. A variety of commenters
support such a prohibition, primarily based on their belief that a rule
against site commissions is needed to ensure that ICS rates are fair,
just, and reasonable. Other commenters, primarily sheriffs and others
associated with correctional facilities, favor the continued use of
site commissions. As noted above, many of these parties, however,
appear to be concerned mostly with ensuring that facilities can recover
costs they incur in allowing access to ICS. As a threshold matter, as
noted herein the record is not clear as to whether the correctional
facilities in fact bear a cost in the provision of ICS that is unique
to the provision of phone service in addition to the costs of operating
a correctional facility. The record suggests that site commissions are
used mainly to fund a wide and disparate range of activities, including
general governmental or correctional activities unrelated to the costs
of providing ICS by either the provider or facility. Even assuming
facilities do incur costs tied to the provision of ICS, we have
addressed such a concern by not prohibiting providers from sharing
their profits with correctional facilities to recover such costs, if
appropriate. Some of these commenters also argue that site commissions
should be preserved because they provide an important incentive for
facilities to make ICS available to their inmates. Another group of
commenters question the Commission's legal authority to prohibit site
commissions and argue that prohibiting site commissions would not
produce any material benefit. A number of commenters, representing a
wide range of interests, urge the Commission to follow the lead of the
Alabama PSC and restrict site commissions only indirectly, by imposing
caps on ICS providers' rates, thereby limiting the amount of profit
available to pay site commissions. The Wright Petitioners, among
others, suggest that we adopt a similar approach here, arguing that the
Commission should ``simply establish an ICS rate that complies with
Sections 201, 205, and 276 of the Act, and let ICS providers and
correctional authorities allocate the revenue in any manner they
wish.'' ICS provider NCIC ``agrees that jails and prisons should be
allowed [to seek] site commission payments after the FCC caps the
rates, ancillary fees and convenience payment options, which will
reduce commission payments to reasonable levels to provide cost-
recovery.'' GTL disagrees, however, arguing that under the Alabama
model, ``providers must generate revenue to pay the unconstrained site
commissions . . . which puts upward pressure on end-user prices.'' In
fact, GTL and others contend that a regulatory regime that permitted
providers to make site commission payments, but did not take those
payments into account in setting the rates would result in an
unconstitutional ``taking'' in violation of the Fifth Amendment, and is
``arbitrary and capricious.''
128. Based on the evidence in the record, we conclude that we do
not need to prohibit site commissions at this time to achieve the
statutory directives of ensuring that ICS rates are just, reasonable,
and fair. The fact that we do not prohibit site commission payments
does not mean, however, that we have failed to address site
commissions. To the contrary, we have addressed the harmful effects of
outsized site commissions by establishing comprehensive rate caps and
caps on ancillary service charges that may limit providers' ability to
pass site commissions through to ICS consumers. We have also made the
considered decision to establish caps on rates and ancillary service
charges and allow market forces to dictate adjustments in site
commission payments. As noted below, this approach is consistent with
the Commission's general preference to rely on market forces, rather
than regulatory intervention, wherever reasonably possible. Our
expectation that ICS providers and correctional facilities will find an
approach that meets their needs and complies with our rate caps is
neither arbitrary nor capricious. In fact, evidence in the record
demonstrates that ICS rates can be set at levels that are well within
our rate caps while allowing for fair compensation and still leaving
room for site commission payments. For example, in Pennsylvania, the
per-minute rate of $0.059 includes a 35 percent site commission.
Similarly, in New Hampshire, the state DOC lowered intrastate rates to
less than $0.06 per minute with a 20 percent site commission. Thus, it
is possible to have reasonable rates and fair compensation without
expressly prohibiting site commissions.
129. We emphasize that the actions we take here are based on our
ratemaking authority and are intended to ensure fair, just, and
reasonable ICS rates. The caps and restrictions we impose on providers'
rates should eliminate or substantially reduce the ability of site
commissions to inflate rates above providers' costs or reasonable
profit to otherwise distort ICS rates. As explained elsewhere in this
Order, we have seen some positive steps toward the lowering and/or
elimination of site commissions and we believe that this trend, coupled
with the actions we take today, constitutes a reasonable means of
addressing ICS issues one step at a time, given the fact that some
portion of some site commissions are said to represent the recovery of
reasonable institutional
[[Page 79154]]
costs. We reiterate that we will, however, continue to monitor the ICS
market and will not hesitate to take additional action to prohibit site
commissions, if necessary.
130. Our decision not to prohibit site commission payments should
not be viewed as an endorsement of such practices. Rather, our decision
simply reflects our focus on achieving our statutory objectives with
only limited regulatory intervention. We understand the positions of
those parties calling for the regulation of site commission practices,
or even those calling for a complete ban of them. We also acknowledge
that some commenters have questioned our legal authority to prohibit
site commissions. Other parties argue that we have clear authority to
regulate site commission payments. Ultimately, however, we do not need
to determine whether we have authority to ban site commission payments,
given our decision to take a less heavy-handed approach, similar to
that adopted by the Alabama PSC. This approach is consistent with the
Commission's general preference to rely on market forces, rather than
regulatory fiat, whenever possible.
131. We expect that the approach adopted in this Order will result
in lower site commissions, and strongly encourage additional
jurisdictions to eliminate site commissions altogether to help ensure
that inmates and their families have access to ICS at affordable rates.
We applaud recent efforts by New Jersey and Ohio to eliminate site
commissions. The per-minute intrastate ICS rates in these states have
dropped considerably (from $0.15 to under $0.05 in New Jersey and $0.39
to $0.05 in Ohio). Pay Tel estimates that in eight states that have
eliminated site commissions the rates average less than $0.07/minute.
The actions taken by these states demonstrate that site commissions can
be eliminated without sacrificing facilities' ability to implement
robust security protocols. Additional states continue to take similar
steps to curb or prevent the use of site commissions in their state
prison systems and we urge other states to take similar actions. We
also reiterate that rates can be significantly below our rate caps and
still offer ICS providers sufficient profit to allow them to pay
reasonable site commissions.
132. Further, we note that, despite what some entities appear to
suggest, this Order does not maintain the status quo in the ICS market.
To the contrary, we conclude that our actions in this Order constitute
changes in law and/or instances of force majeure that are likely to
alter or trigger the renegotiation of many ICS contracts. We also think
it reasonable to anticipate that ICS providers are on notice of these
changes in law and, going forward, will not enter into contracts
promising exorbitant site commission payments that they will not be
able to recover through their ICS rates under our rate caps. Indeed, we
anticipate that the reforms adopted in this Order will help recalibrate
ICS market competition by motivating correctional facilities to
evaluate bids based on factors other than the highest site commission.
However, as noted above, we will monitor the market and will take
appropriate action if our prediction proves inaccurate.
a. Facility Costs Related To Providing ICS
133. Background. In the Mandatory Data Collection, the Commission
required ICS providers to submit their costs related to the provision
of ICS, including their telecommunications, equipment and security
costs. For example, in the Mandatory Data Collection Instructions, the
Bureau directed ICS providers to include ``security costs incurred by
the ICS provider in the provision of inmate calling services, such as,
but not limited to, voice biometrics technology and call recording and
monitoring.'' In their responses, ICS providers indicated that the data
they filed included costs associated with security features relating to
the provision of ICS.
134. In the Second FNPRM, the Commission noted that the record to-
date was mixed regarding how much, if anything, facilities spend on
ICS. It sought comment on the ``actual costs'' that facilities may
incur in the provision of ICS and the appropriate vehicle for enabling
facilities to recover such costs. The Commission also sought comment on
whether any such costs should be recoverable through the per-minute
rates ICS providers charge inmates and their families. In response,
some law enforcement representatives assert that correctional
facilities incur costs related to ``call monitoring, responding to ICS
system alerts, responding to law enforcement requests for records/
recordings, call recording analysis, enrolling inmates for voice
biometrics, and other duties,'' including ``administrative duties''
that arguably are related to ICS. Some ICS providers, however, contend
that many of the activities the facilities claim as ICS-related costs
are, in fact, handled by the ICS provider. For example, Securus states
that it performs most ICS-related tasks for facilities, including
handling U.S. Marshal inquiries, cell phone detection and interception,
listening to calls, and providing call recordings to courts. Similarly,
GTL explains that the ``established industry protocol'' is for ICS
providers to handle security duties for the correctional facilities
they serve, either as part of a turnkey ICS product or as a condition
of the contract award, regardless of the size of the facility.
135. Although some commenters argue that allowing ICS creates costs
for facilities, others question whether correctional facilities incur
any costs that should be passed on to consumers as part of the per-
minute rates for ICS. One issue is whether the costs parties seek to
attribute to ICS are, in fact, costs that facilities would incur
regardless of whether they allowed ICS. Andrew Lipman, for example,
argues that many correctional facilities seek payment for ``activities
that have nothing to do with the provision of a telecommunications
service.'' These parties argue that the costs facilities seek to pass
on to ICS providers and users are more properly classified as law
enforcement costs related to operating a correctional facility that
should be borne by the government and not ICS users.
136. Even commenters asserting that facilities incur costs that are
properly attributable to the provision of ICS do not agree on the
extent of those costs. A group of the largest ICS providers, for
example, notes that while they support the recovery of ``legitimate
costs incurred by correctional facilities that are directly related to
the provision of inmate calling services,'' they cannot agree on how
those costs should be calculated. The NSA suggests that the Commission
approve a ``compensation amount for the security and administrative
duties performed in jails in connection with ICS that is an additive
amount to the ICS rate.'' Relying, in large part, on the results of a
survey it took of its members, as well as analyses submitted by other
parties, NSA suggests that this additive amount should range from $0.01
to $0.11 per minute, depending on the size of the facility being
served.
137. Several commenters offer critiques of NSA's survey data,
however. GTL's economic consultant, for example, concludes that NSA's
latest proposal would offer facilities ``significantly larger'' annual
compensation than would be justified by estimates derived from the
analyses conducted by itself and other parties, particularly for small
facilities such as jails with an ADP below 350. Even Pay Tel, which
generally supported the NSA's survey as a ``robust and significant
dataset,'' agrees that NSA failed to remove outliers from its
calculations and that NSA included
[[Page 79155]]
costs that are ``typically associated with on-going investigations that
would not be considered for Cost Recovery purposes.'' Andrew Lipman
notes that the NSA survey was based on only three months of data from
only approximately five percent of NSA's members and that NSA had not
provided any indication of whether the survey respondents were
representative of NSA's broader membership. Mr. Lipman also points out
that the NSA did not provide the raw data, a copy of the survey, any
information on the methodology used by members to allocate time, or
detailed descriptions of the tasks encompassed by various categories of
costs, such as ``administrative,'' ``security'' or ``other.'' Relying
on other evidence in the record, Mr. Lipman suggests that it would be
unreasonable for providers to agree to pay more than $0.01-$0.03 per
minute to reimburse facilities for any costs they may incur in agreeing
to make ICS available to inmates. Darrell Baker of the Alabama PSC
recommends a cost recovery rate of $0.04 per minute for jails of all
sizes and $0.01 to $0.02 per minute for prisons, while an earlier
analysis from GTL yields median cost recovery rates of $0.005 per
minute for prisons and $0.016 per minute for jails.
138. Discussion. The record contains a wide range of conflicting
views regarding whether correctional facilities incur any costs that
are directly and reasonably related to making ICS available and that
must be recovered through ICS rates. As at least one commenter points
out, ICS continues to be offered in states that have prohibited
payments from ICS providers to facilities. This evidence undermines
claims that facilities incur unique costs that are attributable to ICS
and that must be recovered from ICS rates. These claims are further
undermined by the fact that ``[n]one of the correctional facilities and
associations submitted sufficient detail in this proceeding to support
the amount of their alleged costs, or to demonstrate that these costs
meet the used and useful standard.''
139. Some commenters argue that the costs claimed by facilities are
``basic law enforcement activities [such as surveillance and
investigation of calls] and not costs for providing a
telecommunications service.'' The record is not clear that the costs
facilities claim to incur due to ICS would actually be eliminated if
the facilities ceased to allow inmates to have access to ICS. Moreover,
providers indicate that costs that facilities claim to incur in
allowing ICS are, in fact, borne directly by the providers. Those costs
are already built into our rate cap calculations and should not be
recovered through an ``additive'' to the ICS rates. Accordingly, while
we strongly encourage the elimination of site commission payments, we
do not dictate what an ICS provider can do with its profits and
conclude that the most reasonable and fair approach is to leave it to
ICS providers and facilities to negotiate the amount of any payments
from the providers to the facilities, provided that those payments do
not drive the provider's rates above the applicable rate cap. We note,
however, that evidence submitted in the record--and discussed above--
indicates that if facilities incurred any legitimate costs in
connection with ICS, those costs would likely amount to no more than
one or two cents per billable minute. Our rate caps are sufficiently
generous to cover any such costs.
140. As noted above, some parties contend that correctional
facilities will remove or limit access to telephones if the Commission
acts to limit site commission payments. We find it highly unlikely,
however, that facilities would eliminate or limit access to ICS as a
result of this Order. Given that we do not ban site commissions,
facilities have no basis for taking such extreme measures. Notably, the
record contains no indication that ICS deployment has decreased in
states that have eliminated site commissions. This is unsurprising,
given what we anticipate would be an intensely negative backlash to
such an action. In addition, the record indicates that ICS provides
valuable, non-monetary benefits to correctional facilities, such as
correctional management and incentives to inmates who exhibit good
behavior.
b. Ensuring Fair Compensation
141. Some parties argue that it would be confiscatory for the
Commission to exclude the costs of site commission payments from our
rate cap calculations without also explicitly prohibiting ICS providers
from paying such commissions. According to these parties, ICS providers
will not be able to afford the site commission payments demanded of
them by correctional facilities if the providers' revenues are limited
by the rate caps established here. These claims rest largely on the
fact that existing ICS contracts may obligate providers to pay site
commissions to the facilities they are serving. As explained further
below, we conclude that these concerns are largely unfounded.
142. For the same reasons set forth in the 2013 Order, we reject
arguments that the reforms we adopt herein effectuate unconstitutional
takings. The offering of ICS is voluntary on the part of ICS providers,
who are in the best position to decide whether to bid to offer service
subject to the contours of the request for proposal (RFP). There is no
obligation on the part of the ICS provider to submit bids or to do so
at rates that would be insufficient to meet the costs of serving the
facility or result in unfair compensation. We also reiterate that our
rate caps are based on the reported costs that the providers themselves
submitted into the record without any adjustment by the Commission.
Thus, the rate caps provide ample room for an economically efficient
provider of ICS to earn a reasonable profit on its services. The fact
that our rate caps do not include an explicit allowance for site
commission payments does not render them confiscatory. As explained
above, the record does not support a conclusion that site commission
payments are costs that are ``reasonably related to the provision of
ICS.'' The fact that providers choose to pay site commissions is not
enough to render them compensable through the ICS rate, particularly in
light of section 276's requirement that ICS compensation must be
``fair.'' Excluding site commission payments from the rate cap
calculation is no different than excluding any other cost that is not
reasonably related to the provision of the service. For example, if a
provider decided to purchase a fleet of private jets to ferry its
executives from place to place, we would not prohibit such an
expenditure, but--because the purchase of private jets is not
``reasonably related'' to the provision of ICS--we would not include
such an expense in the costs used to determine a fair compensation rate
for ICS.
143. In addition, we re-emphasize that a party carries a heavy
burden if it seeks to demonstrate that a regulation creates an
unconstitutional ``taking.'' For instance, to succeed on a ``takings''
claim, a party must demonstrate that the losses caused by the
regulation in question are so significant that the ``net effect'' is
confiscatory. When confronted with a ``takings'' claim, courts will
examine the net effect of the regulation on the company's enterprise as
a whole, rather than on a specific product or service. Thus, it is not
enough for a provider to show that it is losing money on a particular
service or in serving a particular customer. Instead, a provider
seeking to show that our rate caps are confiscatory will have to
demonstrate that any cognizable harm caused by our regulations is so
severe that it meets the high bar for a takings with respect to the
company as a whole, e.g., by ``destroying the value of [the provider's]
[[Page 79156]]
property for all the purposes for which it was acquired.'' Moreover,
providers have been on notice for years that the Commission might adopt
rate caps, or even eliminate site commissions. Thus, any claims that
our actions today upset ``investment-backed expectations of ICS
providers'' are likely to fail, particularly claims from providers that
recently entered into new contracts with high site commissions in an
effort to circumvent possible Commission regulations. We find it
unlikely that our rates will result in a ``taking,'' but the waiver
process described below should offer providers an adequate avenue for
relief if they find our ICS regulations unworkable.
C. Ancillary Service Charges and Taxes
1. Background
144. The record contains evidence that ancillary service charges
have increased since the 2013 Order, which highlights the fact that,
absent reform, ICS providers have the ability and incentive to continue
to increase such charges unchecked by competitive forces. Indeed, the
continuing growth in the number and dollar amount of ancillary service
charges represents another example of market failure necessitating
Commission action. These charges are unchecked by market forces because
inmates and their families must either incur them when making a call or
forego contact with their loved ones. Ancillary service charges inflate
the effective price consumers pay for ICS. According to some estimates,
ancillary service charges may represent as much as 38 percent of total
consumer ICS payments. The sheer number of ancillary service charges,
their varying nomenclature, and the variability of the amounts charged
make for a confusing system.
145. The record overwhelmingly supports the need to reform
ancillary service charges. While we would prefer to allow the market to
discipline rates, the evidence since the Commission's 2013 Order
confirms that ancillary service charges have not only increased, but
new charges have appeared. We find our statutory directive requires us
to adopt reforms to limit ancillary service charges. As described
below, we adopt caps for certain ancillary fees, and we prohibit all
other charges that are ancillary to ICS.
146. Our Mandatory Data Collection confirmed that various ICS
providers charge a plethora of ancillary service charges, and that
different providers may describe the same charge by different names.
Commenters suggest that ancillary service charges inflate the cost of
ICS to end users without justification. For example, some providers
charge account set-up, maintenance, closure, and refund fees. Praeses
contends that ``[p]roviders should not be permitted to charge any
ancillary fees to recover . . . intrinsic ICS costs, such as validation
fees or fees related to Facility-required security.'' This distinction
between what is an intrinsic part of providing ICS, and what is not,
has helped us to select the ancillary service charges we find
appropriate and to ban all other ancillary service charges.
147. In responding to the unique challenges posed by escalating
ancillary fees, this Order establishes a limited list of ancillary fees
that the Commission will permit ICS providers to charge. The amount of
each of these fees is capped, and ICS providers are restricted from
charging any ancillary fees not specifically allowed in our Order. For
fees for single-call and related services and third-party financial
transaction fees, we allow providers to pass through only the charges
they incur without any additional markup. We limit automated payment
fees to $3.00, live agent fees to $5.95, and paper statement fees to
$2.00. Apart from these specific fees, no additional ancillary service
charges are allowed. Taxes are discussed separately and must be passed
through with no markup. We also take action to avoid potential
loopholes in these rules, such as artificial limits on minimum and
maximum account balances that could require inmates to reload accounts
frequently and unnecessarily increase costs borne by consumers. This
approach involved analyzing the data submitted by carriers, as well as
comments in the record, to determine which fees ICS providers should
legitimately be able to charge end users.
2. Discussion
148. Review of Ancillary Service Charges in the Record. In response
to the Mandatory Data Collection, the Commission received some data
regarding ancillary service charges, but providers did not follow
consistent approaches in assessing and labeling such fees, and
allocated and reported these costs in inconsistent ways. Accordingly,
in the Second FNPRM the Commission sought comment on these data
inconsistencies and on the ancillary service charge data generally. The
Commission also sought comment on prohibiting separate ancillary
service charges for functions that are typically part of normal utility
overhead and should be included in the rate for any basic ICS offering,
and asked if certain types of ancillary service charges, such as refund
charges, should be disallowed altogether.
149. In response to the Second FNPRM, commenters disagreed over the
exact nature of the reforms that should be implemented, but the
majority agreed that many or all ancillary service charges should be
eliminated. ICS provider CTEL claims that ancillary service charges,
not site commissions, drive high ICS calling rates. ICS users also
supported reforming ancillary service charges with examples of the
impact of such charges on their ability to make calls. Even when
consumers are made aware of the fees, they can still seem unjustified
or unclear. The record indicates that ICS providers can receive fair
compensation and provide secure services with a simplified ancillary
service charge structure.
150. Prohibiting Ancillary Service Charges. The Commission sought
comment on prohibiting ancillary service charges altogether. Certain
parties argued that the best approach to ancillary service charges was
to ban them outright. The Wright Petitioners, for example, contend that
no cost data in the record justifies the existence of ancillary fees,
and that ancillary fees differ significantly among providers for no
reason except that ICS providers will charge as much as they can. If
the Commission does not eliminate ancillary service charges, then the
Wright Petitioners contend that any rules addressing ancillary service
charges must specifically identify the fees that may be charged and
prohibit all others. PLS argues the Commission should prohibit
ancillary service charges because many of these fees bear no relation
to ICS costs.
151. Reducing Categories of Ancillary Service Charges. The
Commission also sought comment on limiting the number of allowable
ancillary service charges. Many commenters support this approach as
enabling ICS providers to still earn a profit, while providing their
services at just and reasonable rates. CenturyLink explains that ``the
overall cost of ICS to inmate families will not be reduced without
restrictions on ancillary fees'' and recommends that the Commission
``eliminate all but a narrow class of ancillary fees and impose
reasonable rate caps on those that it allows.'' One commenter explains
that ancillary fees have ``no actual relation to actual costs borne by
ICS providers and have become a mechanism by which providers sustain or
increase their overall revenues.'' Indeed, even ICS providers have
recognized the need for reform and have submitted various proposals to
that end.
[[Page 79157]]
152. Parties differ about which ancillary service charges should be
capped. For example, a number of commenters believe that the Commission
should eliminate all fees for services that a consumer is required to
pay in order to access basic ICS, including, but not limited to,
account set-up, maintenance, funding, refund, and closure fees. In
addition, Praeses suggests that ``[a]ll costs that Providers
necessarily and unavoidably incur as part of completing an inmate call
should be recovered through ICS rates. As a result, Providers should
not be permitted to charge any ancillary fees to recover such intrinsic
ICS costs, such as validation fees or fees related to Facility-required
security.''
153. Of additional concern is the ability of ICS providers to evade
any limitation on a particular ancillary service charge simply by
changing its name. ICSolutions notes that if an RFP for ICS prohibits a
specific fee, some bidding ICS providers simply rename it or create a
new fee to take its place. Other commenters contend that if ICS
providers want to impose additional ancillary service charges, then
they should ask for a waiver from the Commission or a rule
modification.
154. This concerns us because it suggests that ICS providers are
using ancillary service charges as a loophole to increase revenues and
undermine the impact of the interstate rate caps adopted in the 2013
Order. Illustrating the impact this trend has on consumers, Pay Tel
explains that if a family has $100 to spend on inmate calling for the
month, ancillary fees can consume up to $60, leaving only $40 for the
actual phone calls. Ancillary fees often increase the average cost of a
15-minute call to as much as $8.33, more than double the price of a 15-
minute call at the Commission's interim rate caps adopted in the 2013
Order. Some commenters also raise concerns that some ICS providers may
impose unfair rates by instituting minimum or maximum amounts that may
be deposited for prepaid calling accounts.
155. Proposals in the Record. The Commission has focused on market
failure with regard to unchecked and escalating ancillary service
charges in this proceeding, including releasing a public notice prior
to the 2013 Order seeking additional information about this topic.
Since 2012, the Commission has received several proposals detailing
comprehensive ICS reform approaches, and had the benefit of observing
real world models regulating ancillary service charges.
156. Alabama PSC Reforms. In the Second FNPRM, the Commission noted
that the Alabama PSC had implemented an approach to ancillary service
charges that both limited the kinds of allowable ancillary service
charges and capped the fees for those charges. Specifically, the
Alabama PSC authorized, but capped, separate ancillary service charges
for particular services, including a $3.00 maximum fee for debit/credit
card payment, $5.95 maximum fee for payment via live agent, $3.00
maximum cap for bill processing for collect calls billed by a call
recipient's local telecommunications service provider, $5.95 maximum
cap on third-party payment services, five percent cap on inmate
canteen/trust fund transfers, and a $2.00 maximum cap on paper billing
statements. The Commission sought comment on this approach.
157. In the Second FNPRM, the Commission specifically asked whether
the Alabama PSC's rate caps for credit card payments ($3.00 maximum)
and live operator assisted payments ($5.95) would be appropriate for
the Commission to adopt. Many commenters seeking to reform ancillary
service charges focused not only on reducing the kinds of ancillary
service charges that may be imposed, but also on imposing caps on the
fees that may be charged for the approved ancillary service charges.
Some commenters expressed concern that unreasonable costs would
continue to be passed through to end users if regulations only
specified the ancillary service charges that may be levied, without
also imposing caps on those charges.
158. Joint Provider Proposal. In the Second FNPRM, the Commission
also sought comment on the Joint Provider Proposal's suggestions for
ancillary service charge reform. This proposal would voluntarily
eliminate a number of types of fees, including per-call fees, account
set-up fees, billing statement fees, account close-out and refund fees,
wireless administration fees, voice biometrics and other technology
fees, and regulatory assessment fees, and cap charges for non-
eliminated fees. The Joint Provider Proposal supported a $7.95 cap for
three years on debit/credit card payment or deposit fees, a cap for
three years at existing fees (as high as $14.99) for calls billed to a
credit card and as high as $9.99 for calls billed to a mobile phone,
and a cap on money transfer fees at the existing level (as high as
$11.95), plus a $2.50 administrative fee cap. Joint Provider Proposal
supporters claim that their proposal will ``dramatically alter the
economic landscape of the ICS industry, making it possible for
providers to forego many fees and cap others at current levels.''
159. Some commenters criticize the Joint Provider Proposal as
retaining the most lucrative ancillary service charges, and undermining
reform efforts by allowing the large providers to maintain their
dominant positions. CTEL asserts that smaller ICS providers lack the
market power to impose high ancillary service charges. The Alabama PSC
also states that it ``cannot emphasize strongly enough that the
outliers in terms of excessive ancillary fees are the providers that
submitted the Proposal to the Commission.''
160. Pay Tel Proposal. On October 3, 2014, Pay Tel submitted an ex
parte describing a proposal for comprehensive reform, including rate
reform, a proposed approach for site commission payments, reporting
requirements, and a proposal for ancillary service charge reform. The
Commission sought comment on this proposal in the Second FNPRM. The
Wright Petitioners agree with Pay Tel that there should be specific
guidelines for the disclosure of rate and ancillary fee information.''
The Alabama PSC, Wright Petitioners, CenturyLink, and NCIC agree with
Pay Tel's suggested ancillary service charge rate caps in a number of
respects. Securus, however, argues that Pay Tel mischaracterizes the
Joint Provider Proposal, and that, to justify its own proposal, Pay Tel
grossly overestimates the amount of ancillary service charges that
consumers will have to pay under the Joint Provider Proposal.
3. Establishing Limited List of Permitted Ancillary Service Charges
161. After careful consideration of the record, including analysis
of the Mandatory Data Collection, we conclude that reform is necessary
to address ever-increasing fees that are unchecked by competitive
forces and unrelated to costs. ICS providers, which typically have
exclusive contracts to serve a facility, have the incentive and ability
to continue to extract unjust and unreasonable ancillary service
charges. As a result, we conclude it is necessary to reform the
ancillary service charge structure imposed on consumers by ICS
providers, as shown in Table Four below. All other ancillary service
charges not specifically included in Table Four are prohibited. (Thus,
providers would be prohibited from imposing charges for biometric
technology, for example.) We conclude that the allowable charges will
facilitate communications between inmates and their loved ones and will
allow ICS providers to recover the costs incurred for providing the
ancillary service associated with the relevant fee. We find no other
examples in the record of
[[Page 79158]]
ancillary services that are actually provided today and that have a
cost that warrants recovery.
162. Our approach is supported by the record and will reduce the
cost of service for millions of consumers. Even so, as with all reforms
adopted in this Order, we will reevaluate these charges in two years to
determine if adjustments are appropriate. We expect that these caps
will serve as backstops as efficiencies are gained by providers, and
contracts are changed, or new contracts are entered into between
parties. For example, the record indicates that the recently-adopted
New Jersey state correctional institutions' ICS contract specifically
prohibits ``discretionary fees,'' which include bill statement fees,
monthly recurring wireless account maintenance charges, account setup
fees, funding fees, refund fees, and a single bill fee. Finally, we
believe it is reasonable to expect that the ancillary service charge
caps may encourage providers to more efficiently provide ancillary
services, potentially stimulating competition among ICS providers to
the added benefit of consumers and in keeping with section 276's
statutory mandate. The reforms are intended to facilitate the proper
functioning of the ICS market.
163. Each of the entries in Table Four focuses on the particular
functions related to each type of charge listed below. (Thus, even if a
provider renames one of its fees to match the terminology in this
table, that will not be sufficient to make an allowable ancillary
service charge. Also, each individual ancillary service charge that an
ICS provider levies must serve one of the permitted functions in order
to qualify as a permissible ancillary service charge, regardless of the
precise terminology used. In the event of dispute, the Commission will
evaluate the fee charged to a consumer on the basis of the totality of
the circumstances, judged from a reasonable consumer's point of view,
to determine whether the fee serves one of the permitted functions.
Automated payments include payments by interactive voice response
(IVR), web, and kiosk.)
Table Four
------------------------------------------------------------------------
Permitted ancillary service charges and Monetary cap per use/
taxes instruction
------------------------------------------------------------------------
Applicable taxes and regulatory fees... Provider shall pass these
charges through to consumers
directly with no markup.
Automated payment fees................. $3.00.
Fees for single-call and related Provider shall directly pass
services, e.g., direct bill to mobile through third-party financial
phone without setting up an account. transaction fees with no
markup, plus adopted, per-
minute rate.
Live agent fee, i.e., phone payment or $5.95.
account set up with optional use of a
live operator.
Paper bill/statement fees (no charge $2.00.
permitted for electronic bills/
statements).
Prepaid account funding minimums and Prohibit prepaid account
maximums. funding minimums and prohibit
prepaid account funding
maximums under $50.
Third-party financial transaction fees, Provider shall pass this charge
e.g., MoneyGram, Western Union, credit through to end user directly,
card processing fees and transfers with no markup.
from third-party commissary accounts.
------------------------------------------------------------------------
164. Data Analysis. Based on our analysis of the ancillary service
charge cost data submitted in response to the Mandatory Data Collection
and the record, we conclude that the caps we adopt for ancillary
service charges will allow ICS providers to recover their reported
costs attributable to providing these services and earn fair
compensation. Ten of the fourteen ICS providers that submitted data in
response to the Mandatory Data Collection included cost and revenue
data for ancillary service charges. One provider did not report any
direct costs related to ancillary service charges and one provider
reported only one ancillary service charge. The reported rates for
ancillary service charges range from $0.08 to $10.97 per use for
automated payments, from $2.49 to $5.95 per use for transactions
handled by a live agent, and from $1.50 to $5.00 for paper billing
fees. In comparison, ICS providers report that they incur costs for
ancillary service charges ranging from $0.10 to $6.58 when they offer
automated payments, $2.49 to $5.26 when they offer transactions handled
by a live agent, and $0.08 to $2.88 when they offer paper billing.
These numbers serve to illustrate the enormous difference between the
charges imposed on ICS end users and the much lower costs to ICS
providers of offering those services. The ancillary service charge caps
we have selected fall within a reasonable range of the reported costs
for the services, and are supported by the record for each fee cap as
explained below.
165. We also note that some jurisdictions have banned ancillary
service charges and that providers have complied with such regulations.
This suggests that ancillary service costs can be recovered with
reasonable ICS rates. Accordingly, our ancillary service charge caps
should more than adequately compensate for the costs incurred.
Moreover, we conclude that the annual reporting, certification and data
collection requirements adopted herein regarding ancillary fee
information will ensure compliance with the requirements. We will use
this information to ensure that ICS providers are complying with the
reforms adopted herein.
166. Ancillary Services Charge Cap Methodology. The reforms we
adopt herein represent a middle ground between the various proposals in
the record. First, we determined which categories of ancillary service
charges should be allowed. Next, we evaluated the information obtained
through our Mandatory Data Collection as discussed above, and comments
in the record addressing the specific proposals in and in response to
the Second FNPRM. We conclude that prohibiting ICS providers from
recovering their costs reasonably and directly related to making
available an ancillary service would not allow ICS providers to receive
fair compensation for those services. We also conclude that certain
proposed high ancillary service charges, such as those in the Joint
Provider Proposal, would result in excessively compensatory fees and
would violate our requirement to make ICS rates just, reasonable and
fair to end users. Therefore, we adopt caps on fees for ancillary
service charges that will allow ICS providers to recover the costs
incurred for providing the ancillary service associated with the
relevant fee while ensuring just, reasonable, and fair
[[Page 79159]]
rates to end users. Below we explain the analysis that went into
determining the appropriate cap for each category of permitted
ancillary service charge.
167. Automated Payment Fee. We permit up to a $3.00 automated
payment fee for credit card, debit card, and bill processing fees,
including payments made by interactive voice response (IVR), web, or
kiosk. This approach is supported by the record and more than ensures
that ICS providers can recoup the costs of offering these services. The
Commission specifically sought comment on automated payment fees in the
Second FNPRM. For example, the Commission asked whether a $3.00 cap for
debit and credit card payment fees via the web, an IVR, or a kiosk was
an appropriate charge. We find support for our approach from numerous
commenters, including the Alabama PSC, which concluded, as we do, that
a $3.00 cap for credit card processing and bill processing is
appropriate. This $3.00 cap is also supported by Pay Tel, which charges
this amount for automated payments. In addition, multiple parties
support this approach in the record, including the Wright Petitioners,
CenturyLink, and NCIC--all of which agree this amount is an appropriate
cap for automated payments. Securus, one of the largest ICS providers
in the market, asserted that allowing end users to pay with credit
cards costs the company more than $3.00. The credit-card processing
costs that Securus cites indicate to us that it is an outlier,
especially since, as just discussed, companies that are much smaller
than Securus acknowledge that they can process credit card payments at
a $3.00 rate. We find that a $3.00 cap on automated payments is
supported by the reported costs of providing the service as opposed to
other rates for the service.
168. Live Agent Payment Fee or Account Set Up. We allow ICS
providers to recover up to $5.95 when consumers choose to make use of
an optional live operator to complete ICS transactions. We have
recognized that interaction with a live operator to complete ICS
transactions may add to the costs of providing ICS. Thus, we allow an
ancillary service charge to compensate providers for offering this
optional service. As with the other ancillary service charges we have
determined are appropriate, in the Second FNPRM, the Commission also
specifically asked commenters about the $5.95 maximum fee for live
operator assisted payments. For the live agent phone payment of $5.95
that we adopt, we note that multiple ICS providers including,
CenturyLink, NCIC, and Pay Tel, as well as the Wright Petitioners, and
the Alabama PSC, all agree that this is the correct rate. This $5.95
fee may only be charged once per interaction with a live operator,
regardless of the number of tasks completed in the call, and live
operator calls may not be terminated in order to attempt to charge this
fee an additional time. We will monitor any complaints we receive with
regard to the live agent fee that suggest that providers are attempting
to circumvent the limitations this rule sets forth.
169. Paper Bill/Statement Fee. We permit a cap of $2.00 for
optional paper billing statements. In the Second FNPRM, the Commission
noted that the Alabama PSC had capped the charge for a paper bill or
statement, and asked commenters to explain whether this, and other
approaches taken by the Alabama PSC, were reasonable and would lead to
just and reasonable rates and fair ICS compensation. Multiple
commenters agreed. Specifically, the $2.00 paper bill charge we adopt
is supported by the Wright Petitioners, Pay Tel, and the Alabama PSC,
while CenturyLink argues that the rate should be marginally higher at
$2.50 per bill.
170. Third-Party Financial Transaction Fee. In the Second FNPRM,
the Commission asked how it should ensure that money transfer service
fees paid by ICS consumers are just and reasonable and fair. The record
establishes that inmates' families frequently do not have bank
accounts, and therefore rely on third-party money transfer services
such as Western Union or MoneyGram to fund calls with inmates. Third-
party financial transaction fees as discussed herein consist of two
elements. The first element is the transfer of funds from a consumer
via the third-party service, i.e., Western Union or MoneyGram, to an
inmate's ICS account. (We use these two services as an example but do
not foreclose the possibility that there are other third-party
financial transaction services. Credit card payment processing also
falls under the discussion here.) The second element is the ICS
provider's additional charge imposed on end users for processing the
funds transferred via the third party provider for the purpose of
paying for ICS calls. We find that this first aspect of third-party
financial transaction, e.g., the money transfers or credit card
payments, does not constitute ``ancillary services'' within the meaning
of section 276. The record suggests that ICS providers have limited
control over the fees established by third parties, such as Western
Union or credit card companies, for payment processing functions.
171. However, the record indicates that ICS providers are imposing
significant additional charges, as high as $11.95, for end users to
make account payments via third parties, such as Western Union or Money
Gram, and sharing the resulting profit with those third-party financial
institutions. We find that the ICS providers' additional fee or mark-up
to the third-parties' service charges function as a billing-and-
collection related charge, on top of the third-party charge, that the
Commission has authority to address. Providers have offered no cost-
based justification for imposing an additional fee on end users on top
of the third-party money-transfer service or financial institution fee,
nor have they explained what (if any) functions they must necessarily
perform to ``process'' a transfer already transferred from the third-
party provider. Therefore, as discussed in more detail below, we
require that ICS providers pass through to their end users, with no
additional markup, the money transfer or third-party financial
transaction fees they are charged by such third parties. (The record
indicates that no additional markup is warranted on top of the fees
charged by the third-party payment providers.)
172. Our adopted approach ensures that, in transactions like these,
ICS providers do not receive excessive compensation, while also
protecting consumers from unreasonable additional fees that result in
unjust and unreasonable ICS rates. We find support for our third-party
financial transaction fee approach from parties such as CenturyLink and
NCIC, and the Alabama PSC additionally urges the Commission to require
ICS providers to ``eliminate the provider ancillary charge premium they
assess on top of the $5.95 payment transfer fee available to their
customers from Western Union and MoneyGram.''
173. Prohibited Fees. As explained above, our approach to fees
charged for ancillary services specifically enumerates the charges
permitted and bans all other ancillary service charges. We find no
other examples in the record of ancillary services that are actually
provided today and that have a cost that warrants recovery. While we
place limits on the types of ancillary service charges we allow, we
note that it is important to have payment options that permit the
consumer simply to pay for service without incurring any additional
charges. Many commenters, including ICS providers, agree that these
basic or standard methods, such as making
[[Page 79160]]
payments by check or money order, must remain available without charge.
Securus, for example, has assured the Commission that ``[p]ayment by
check or money order always will be available and free of charge.'' In
accordance with our decision to allow only the specific ancillary
service charges we enumerate in this Order, we clarify that no charges
are permissible for payment by check or money order.
174. At this time, we do not find it necessary to eliminate all
ancillary service charges to be consistent with our statutory
objectives and policy goals for ICS reform. We are mindful of and
concerned about the potential for continued abuse of ancillary service
charges, and we will monitor the implementation of these caps and
determine if additional reforms are necessary in the future. By
limiting the scope of ancillary service charges, we also resolve other
problems presented in the record. We prohibit all other ancillary
service charges not enumerated because the record did not demonstrate
that any other ancillary services are reasonably and directly related
to the provision of ICS, nor are they necessary to ensure that ICS
providers receive fair compensation for providing service. Permitting
any other ancillary service charges would promote unfair, unjust, and
unreasonable rates to end users, and would thus be contrary to our
statutory mandate. Further, we find that removing a substantial number
of unjustifiable charges not only benefits consumers, but also reduces
compliance costs for ICS providers by allowing them easily to identify
whether a particular charge is permitted by our rules. Additionally,
since we have determined that the only justifiable ancillary service
charges are the ones we specifically enumerated, there are no
countervailing costs that would outweigh our selected approach.
175. Purchase Minimums and Maximums. In the Second FNPRM, the
Commission asked commenters whether anything should be done about
policies, such as funding minimums and maximums that may restrict
consumers' access to ICS. In response, some parties raise concerns that
some ICS providers are engaging in unjust and unreasonable practices
and imposing unfair rates by instituting minimum or maximum amounts
that may be deposited for prepaid calling accounts. CenturyLink, for
example, contends that ``[p]roviders might impose high purchase
minimums and complex refund policies to obtain captured funds.
Providers might also adopt low purchase maximums to force customers to
have to repeatedly re-purchase services and generate transaction
fees.'' Similarly, ICSolutions urges the Commission to regulate minimum
and maximum funding requirements, arguing that high minimum funding
requirements ``can preclude consumers from receiving calls from their
loved ones,'' while low maximums can force consumers to ``fund their
account more frequently, so that [the provider] can charge more
ancillary fee payments.'' Furthermore, NCIC points out that ``payments
for prepaid service by money order or check [are] available free of
charge to ICS end users but this payment method is frequently
impractical because of the excessive latency involved in establishing
service (up to ten days for some providers).'' Thus, inmates are
essentially forced into entering into more costly prepaid options, many
of which require minimum payments and/or impose maximum limits on
deposits.
176. We agree that high purchase minimum requirements can lead to
unfair compensation by forcing consumers to deposit relatively large
sums of money even if they only want to make one short call or by
driving consumers to more expensive calling options. Thus, high
purchase minimums can effectively allow providers to charge exorbitant
amounts for single calls. Such a result would be antithetical to the
Commission's goals and to the requirements of sections 201 and 276.
177. An artificial limit on maximum account deposits could also
lead to gaming and loopholes. CenturyLink points out that low maximums
on deposits can allow providers to increase transaction fees. A
provider may refuse to permit a consumer from depositing more than a
certain amount of money into an inmate calling account in a single
transaction, thereby compelling the consumer to engage in additional
transactions and, as a result, incur multiple ancillary service
charges. Thus, providers could circumvent our reforms by placing
artificially low limits on deposits and requiring consumers to incur
ancillary charges every time they add additional money to an account.
178. In order to prevent ICS providers from obtaining unfair
compensation by inflating costs for end users relating to maximum and
minimum deposits, we prohibit ICS providers from instituting prepaid
account minimums, and require that any provider that limits deposits to
set the maximum purchase amount at no less than $50 per transaction.
Data from the Mandatory Data Collection show that the average call
length reported by respondents was approximately 13 minutes. Under our
new rate structure, that means the average cost of a call from a prison
would be about $1.43. Accordingly, a $50 maximum per transaction would
mean that consumers will be able to make a relatively large number of
calls with a single deposit (on average about 35 calls). We find that
allowing a lower limit would create an unacceptable risk that providers
would be able to compel consumers to incur multiple ancillary service
charges, as explained above. We note, however, that the record also
reflects concerns that setting the floor for maximum allowable deposits
too low could create risks for ICS providers, including the potential
for fraud. Allowing providers to institute maximum deposit amounts, but
requiring that those maximums be no lower than $50, strikes a
reasonable balance between the competing concerns expressed in the
record. We also note that various providers have instituted maximum
deposit policies that conform to our requirement of no less than a $50
maximum per transaction, and in some circumstances have even instituted
higher maximum deposit limits. As noted below, we will continue to
monitor the ICS marketplace and to investigate any attempts, such as
these, to circumvent our rate caps or our rules governing ancillary
charges. Due to the history of the large number and ever-changing and
growing nature of ancillary service charges, as described in the
record, we will be diligent in identifying any providers that violate
the new rules covering ancillary service charges, third-party financial
transaction fees, and minimum and maximum account funding. Accordingly,
we delegate to the Bureau the authority to clarify the rule as
necessary, after public notice and an opportunity to comment, where
appropriate, to ensure that the reforms adopted in this Order relating
to ancillary service charges and third-party financial transaction fees
are properly reflected. This includes seeking comment on prohibiting
additional ancillary fees if there is evidence of abuse of the
permitted charges.
4. Cost-Benefit Analysis
179. After careful consideration, we find that our approach to
adopt simple ancillary service charge caps provides significant and
important benefits to ICS end users, outweighing any potential burdens
to providers. As discussed above, we conclude that reform is necessary
to address ever-increasing and multiplying fees that are unchecked by
competitive forces and unrelated to costs. We find that the allowable
ancillary service charges will facilitate communications between
inmates and their families, while enabling ICS
[[Page 79161]]
providers to recover the costs incurred for providing the associated
ancillary services.
180. It is clear that market failure exists with regard to
ancillary service charges. Numerous parties cite specific instances of
such market failure or abuse among ancillary service charge categories.
Additionally, commenters request the Commission take action to curb
these abuses by adopting reforms.
181. By creating simple rate caps and limiting the scope of
ancillary service charges, we resolve these problems and reform
ancillary charges. We prohibit all ancillary service charges not
specifically allowed, not only for the foregoing reasons, but also
because the record did not demonstrate that any other ancillary
services are reasonably and directly related to the provision of ICS or
necessary to ensure that ICS providers receive fair compensation for
providing service. Further, we find that removing a substantial number
of unjustifiable charges not only benefits consumers, but also reduces
compliance costs for ICS providers by allowing them easily to identify
whether a particular charge is permitted by our rules, thus reducing
the burden on them. As noted below, however, to minimize any potential
burdens associated with ancillary service charges, we will reevaluate
these charges to determine if adjustments are appropriate.
5. Fees for Single-Call and Related Services
182. Background. The record indicates that single-call and related
services are a growing part of the ICS market. These options, such as
single-call services, are billing arrangements whereby an ICS
provider's collect calls are billed through third-party billing
entities on a call-by-call basis to parties whose carriers do not bill
collect calls. A single-call service thus may be used for calls placed
from the inmate facility to mobile phones or a telecom service where
the called party does not have an account, does not want to establish
an account, or does not know the party can establish an account with
the ICS provider. Although some efficiencies may derive from single-
call and related services, the record is replete with evidence that
some of these services are being used in a manner to inflate charges,
and may be offered at unjust, unreasonable, or unfair rates, and/or at
rates above our interim rate caps or rate caps adopted in this Order.
The record also highlights substantial end-user confusion regarding
single-call services.
183. A significant problem with single-call and related services is
that they end up being among the most expensive ways to make a phone
call. In the Second FNPRM, the Commission sought comment on the
prevalence of single-call services and whether rates for such services
are just and reasonable.
184. There is a diversity of views in the record on single-call and
related services. CPC believes that single-call services should be
treated as ancillary services subject to rate caps and that consumers
must be notified of the option to set up a prepaid account instead.
Several commenters believe that all of these single-call and related
services should be eliminated because they are simply an ``end run''
around the Commission's rate caps. The Wright Petitioners note that any
proposed rate caps should also apply to single-call services, along
with a $3.00 funding fee. PPI also argues that, in the alternative,
charges for single call services should be restricted to a reasonable
deposit fee, plus a reasonable capped call fee. As the Alabama PSC
notes, ``[t]he regulator's duty is to set fair and reasonable rates for
ICS calls.''
185. ICSolutions notes that the single-call or related service
charge is often $9.99 or $14.99, regardless of whether the call lasts
one minute or 10 or 15 minutes, and that these rates are 300 percent or
376 percent higher than the effective interstate rate caps. It contends
that such calls pose a danger to consumers, and that providers
manipulate consumers into selecting these calling options even though
less costly call options may exist. Other providers share ICSolutions'
concern that single-call or related services are used to ``inflate
ancillary fees'' at the expense of end users. CenturyLink, ICSolutions,
and NCIC, among others, expressed concern about the use of third
parties, including unregulated subsidiaries, to provide single-call or
related services at high fees, and about revenue-sharing arrangements
that enable ICS providers to recoup all or a portion of the ancillary
service charge as profit outside our rate caps. Additionally, the
Alabama PSC analyzed these single-call services in a jail, and found
that ``[a]lthough single payment calls account for 14% of the calls and
17% of the minutes at the facility, they are responsible for 42% of all
the revenue generated.'' Conversely, GTL urges the Commission not to
regulate these services, arguing the Commission does not have
jurisdiction to do so. Securus similarly argues that single-call and
related services should not be considered ancillary services because
they are optional and are not intended to be a substitute for
traditional ICS calls. Securus asserts that if the Commission regulates
the rates for single-call and related services, ICS providers will be
forced to stop offering them, and inmates and their friends and
families will have fewer calling options by which to stay in touch.
186. Discussion. We agree with commenters that suggest single-call
and related services are another form of ancillary service charges. The
additional costs stemming from single-call and related services are
ancillary to the provision of ICS because they are additional fees
charged to consumers, based on the consumer's discretion and desire to
make use of such a service because, for example they want to speak to
the incarcerated person as quickly as possible in order to arrange
their release. We therefore believe that reform is necessary and that
it is appropriate to address unreasonable charges. As a result, for
single call and related services, we permit ICS providers to charge the
amount of the third-party financial transaction (with no markup) added
to a per-minute rate no higher than the applicable rate cap. These
reforms are necessary to ensure that when end users decide to take
advantage of single-call and related services, the rates for such calls
comply with the statute.
187. Unlike the ancillary service charge caps adopted above, we do
not find that single-call and related services are reasonably and
directly related to the provision of ICS, but are ancillary to ICS. We
believe that charges for single-call and related services inflate the
effective price end users pay for ICS and result in excessive
compensation to providers. Accordingly, for single-call and related
services, the Commission will allow ICS providers to charge end users
for each single call in a manner consistent with our approach to third-
party financial transaction fees--i.e., ICS providers may charge the
amount of the third-party financial transaction (with no markup) added
to a per-minute rate no higher than the applicable rate cap. This
approach is consistent with our overall approach to reforming both ICS
per-minute rates and ancillary service charges. It will ensure just and
reasonable rates for end users that are based on actual costs incurred
by ICS providers.
188. The record supports our reforms to fees charged for single-
call and related services. We have authority to reform ancillary
service charges and we therefore disagree with ICS providers that argue
we lack authority. Moreover, our approach in no way interferes with
contracts between ICS providers and third-party payment processors or
[[Page 79162]]
mobile phone companies because our rule simply prevents ICS providers
from adding additional fees to the cost of these calls. It does not
dictate what fees an ICS provider itself may choose to pay or not pay
these third parties for services rendered.
189. We have also heard from commenters that a major problem with
single-call and related services is that customers are often unaware
that other payment options are available, such as setting up an
account. To help alleviate the problem of customers continually paying
set up fees for single-call and related service calls, we encourage
providers to make clear to consumers that they have other payment
options available to them. This is consistent with our discussion and
analysis regarding consumer disclosure requirements below. We will
continue to monitor the use of such calling arrangements and seek
specific information about them in the Further Notice of Proposed
Rulemaking published elsewhere in this issue of the Federal Register.
6. Taxes and Regulatory Fees
190. The record in this proceeding indicates that ICS providers
charge ICS end users ``fees under the guise of taxes.'' In an effort to
ensure just, reasonable and fair ICS rates, in the Second FNPRM, the
Commission asked ``whether the cost of regulatory compliance should be
considered a normal cost of doing business and as such should be
recovered through basic ICS rates, not additional ancillary fees.'' In
response, Lattice asserts that ``ICS providers also must be permitted
to continue to collect pass-through charges such as state and local
taxes, universal service and numbering charges, and other federal,
state and local fees.''
191. ICS providers are permitted to recover mandatory applicable
pass-through taxes and regulatory fees, but without any additional
mark-up or fees. The Commission has defined a government mandated
charge as follows: ``amounts that a carrier is required to collect
directly from customers, and remit to federal, state or local
governments.'' Non-mandated charges are defined to be ``government
authorized but discretionary fees, which a carrier must remit pursuant
to regulatory action but over which the carrier has discretion whether
and how to pass on the charge to the consumer.'' Commission precedent
prohibits providers from placing a line item on a carrier's bill that
implies a charge is mandated by the government when it is in fact,
discretionary.
192. We agree that the ability to collect applicable pass-through
taxes and regulatory fees without adding a markup is important and
consistent with precedent. However, we reiterate that it is misleading
``for carriers to state or imply that a charge is required by the
government when it is the carriers' business decision as to whether and
how much of such costs they choose to recover directly from consumers
through a separate line item charge.'' As such, we do not permit fees
or charges beyond mandatory taxes and fees, and authorized fees that
the carrier has the discretion to pass through to consumers without any
mark up. This will help ensure, consistent with the goals of the
reforms adopted in this Order, that ICS end user's rates are just,
reasonable and fair because they are paying the cost of the service
they have chosen and any applicable taxes or fees, and nothing more.
This approach has support in the record, including from the Joint
Provider Proposal and Pay Tel.
7. Legal Authority
193. We reaffirm the Commission's finding in the 2013 Order that it
has jurisdiction over interstate ICS ancillary service charges and
further find that we have authority to reform intrastate ancillary
service charges. The Commission sought comment in the Second FNPRM as
to whether it is also authorized to regulate intrastate ancillary
service charges. In response, several commenters took the position that
section 276 of the Act authorizes the Commission to regulate intrastate
ancillary service charges. We agree.
194. We find that the Commission has the legal authority to adopt
necessary reforms to interstate, intrastate, and international
ancillary service charges. In the 2013 Order, the Commission addressed
interstate charges and found that billing and collection services
provided by a common carrier for its own customers are subject to
section 201, and are therefore, subject to Commission regulation. The
Commission explained that it has jurisdiction ``to regulate the manner
in which a carrier bills and collects for its own interstate offerings,
because such billing is an integral part of that carrier's
communication service.'' We reaffirm that finding here. Thus, providers
are on notice that efforts to circumvent our rate caps through
artificially high ancillary fees will not be tolerated.
195. Although ``ancillary services'' are not defined by statute,
and there is some disagreement in the record on this point, the
dictionary meaning of the term ``ancillary''--``providing necessary
support to the primary activities or operation of an organization,
institution, industry, or system''--is instructive. Additionally,
section 276(b)(1)(A) specifies that any compensation plan set forth by
the Commission must ensure that providers ``are fairly compensated for
each and every completed intrastate and interstate call . . . .''
196. In the discussion above, we find that we have jurisdiction
over intrastate ICS charges, pursuant to section 276 of the Act. We
also note that section 276(d) defines ``payphone service'' as ``the
provision of public or semi-public pay telephones, the provision of
inmate telephone service in correctional institutions, and any
ancillary services.'' Thus, we believe it is clear that Congress
provided the Commission with authority over ICS-related ``ancillary
services.'' Based upon the plain language of these statutory provisions
and the common definition of the term ``ancillary,'' we find that the
term ``ancillary services,'' as used in section 276(d), is reasonably
interpreted to mean services that provide necessary support for the
completion of international, interstate and intrastate calls provided
via ICS. We find that section 276 authorizes the Commission to regulate
charges for intrastate ancillary services, such as billing and
collection services, to the extent those charges involve the completion
of a call, or other communications services. Such charges are quite
literally the ``necessary support'' essential for the completion of
inmate phone calls. Indeed, often the only purpose for establishing ICS
accounts is to fund communication with inmates; therefore, these
charges are reasonably understood to be ancillary to the completion of
phone calls. As such, we conclude that billing-and-collection-related
ancillary services such as account set up and transaction fees fall
within the Commission's jurisdictional authority and will be regulated
in the manner described above.
D. Periodic Review of Reforms
197. While the 2013 Order and today's reforms are a significant
step forward, we are committing to continuing to review the ICS market,
including both costs and rates, to ensure that regulation remains
necessary and that the reforms we adopt herein strike the right
balance. The reforms adopted in this Order may facilitate changes in
the ICS market that potentially could make it function properly and
enable the Commission to reduce regulations. At the same time, changes
in the market, for example, may necessitate additional modifications to
the reform we adopt today. We will incorporate lessons learned from the
prior data collection to
[[Page 79163]]
improve quality and eliminate anomolies. While the policies adopted in
this Order have been carefully designed based on the record before us,
we remain dedicated to evaluating how changing circumstances impact the
nature and scope of reform. The Commission has the authority to take
steps to effectively monitor compliance with this Order going forward.
198. To enable the Commission to take further ICS reform action,
identify and track trends in the ICS market, as well as monitor
compliance with the reforms adopted herein, we adopt a second, one-time
Mandatory Data Collection to occur two years from publication of Office
of Management and Budget (OMB) approval of the information collection.
We believe it is appropriate to be able to conduct a review of the ICS
market including ICS costs, rates and ancillary service charges to
ensure that any regulations continue to be necessary to fulfill our
statutory objectives and to ensure that any such reforms and rate caps
reflect current market dynamics and costs.
199. In the Second FNPRM, the Commission sought comment on the
benefits of establishing a review process. The Commission also sought
comment on the Wright Petitioners' suggestion that the Commission
commit to review the interim rates adopted in the 2013 Order. In its
comments, HRDC states generally that periodic reviews by the Commission
to evaluate the ways in which ICS reforms impact phone rates, ancillary
service charges and competition in the industry are ``essential to
ensure that the reforms create and maintain the proper incentives to
drive ICS rates to competitive levels.''
200. We find that, on balance, Petitioners' proposal for a periodic
review of ICS data is not necessary at this time, nor is it the best
tool for monitoring compliance with the Order. Therefore, we establish
a less onerous requirement, which we anticipate will provide
significant benefit at minimal cost. In lieu of the Petitioners'
proposal, we adopt an approach similar to the one used by the
Commission in a prior payphone order establishing the per-call rate for
payphones, in which the Commission determined that it would ``have to
periodically review the cost-based compensation rate in order to ensure
that it continues to `fairly compensate' PSPs and promote payphone
competition and widespread deployment of payphones.'' The Commission
explained that, ``[e]specially when market conditions have changed
significantly, it is incumbent upon us to reexamine whether the
conditions resulting in the recent Commission-prescribed rate still
apply.'' As with that situation, we conclude that the Commission should
have the tools necessary to review the reforms that we adopt in this
Order, in light of changing market conditions, to ensure that the rates
continue to be just, reasonable, and fair. As explained above,
ancillary service charges also significantly impact the effective rates
ICS providers charge, and should therefore be part of this review.
201. To allow for consistent data reporting and to prevent
duplicative filings, we direct the Bureau to develop a template for
submitting the data and provide ICS providers with further instructions
to implement the data collection. We direct the Bureau to complete a
review of ICS costs and rates within one year from the date data is
submitted, and we delegate to the Bureau authority to require an ICS
provider to submit such data as the Bureau deems necessary to perform
its review. Information in response to the forthcoming data collection
may be filed under the Protective Order in this proceeding and will be
treated as confidential.
202. Several commenters have expressed concern for the lack of
transparency regarding ICS rates and fees. We share the concern that
ICS contracts are not sufficiently transparent and we find adequate
evidence, such as numerous public records lawsuits, to support HRDC's
assertion that members of the public must ``unnecessarily expend time
and money to obtain records'' of ICS contracts. We also recognize
evidence suggesting that the information regarding ICS contracts and
rates that is publically available may not be reliable. Therefore, we
encourage ICS providers and facilities to make their contracts publicly
available.
E. Harmonization With State ICS Rules and Requirements
203. Below, we provide guidance to ICS providers, correctional
facilities and state regulatory bodies on the effect of the
comprehensive reforms adopted herein on ICS requirements in the states
and the Commission's authority to regulate these services pursuant to
section 276 of the Communications Act.
1. Background
204. In the 2013 Order, the Commission sought comment on its
tentative conclusion that section 276 ``affords the Commission broad
discretion to regulate intrastate ICS rates and practices . . . and to
preempt inconsistent state requirements.'' Commenters' responses were
mixed. The Commission then followed up by seeking more focused comments
on issues related to preemption and harmonization of state ICS
requirements. Several commenters support preemption of state laws and
requirements that are inconsistent with the federal regime, while a
small number of commenters oppose such preemption and question our
authority to preempt state requirements related to intrastate ICS. As
discussed below, we now adopt the tentative conclusion the Commission
first expressed in the 2013 Order, and hold that we have the authority
to preempt state requirements that are inconsistent with the rules we
adopt in this Order. More specifically, we conclude that a state
requirement that ICS be provided at a particular rate that exceeds the
caps we have adopted would trigger change-in-law provisions or require
renegotiation. If for some reason that does not occur for any
particular contract, parties can file a petition with the Commission
seeking the appropriate relief. State rates below our rate caps or
ancillary fee caps will not be preempted.
205. The rate caps and reforms adopted herein should operate as a
ceiling in areas where states have not enacted reforms. This is
consistent with Commission precedent in which it has determined that
rates at or below a newly-enacted rate cap were not to be changed. We
strongly encourage all states to evaluate additional measures to reduce
and eliminate site commissions and ensure that rates for inmate calling
services are as low as possible while still ensuring that robust
security protocols are in place. Our actions today serve to ensure that
a much-needed default framework is in place in areas where states have
not acted to curb ICS rates.
206. In the Second FNPRM, the Commission sought comment on a number
of issues related to the preemption of state regulation of ICS, as well
as the potential to harmonize state requirements that are inconsistent
with the Commission's comprehensive framework for regulation of both
interstate and intrastate ICS. Among other questions, the Commission
sought comment on its belief that it has ``broad discretion to find
that a particular state requirement, or category of state requirements,
is either consistent or inconsistent with Commission ICS regulations
under section 276(c)'' and to preempt those regulations that are
inconsistent.
207. Several commenters support preemption, urging the Commission
to establish a uniform framework for both interstate and intrastate
ICS. ICS
[[Page 79164]]
provider Lattice, for example, argues that ``[s]ound public policy as
well as the Communications Act and FCC precedent all support FCC reform
across all ICS.'' Lattice contends not only that ``[s]ection 276 grants
the Commission express authority to preempt state requirements to the
extent they are inconsistent with FCC regulations,'' but that
``preemption of state regulation is required to fulfill the
requirements of section 276.'' Pay Tel also argues that the Commission
has authority over intrastate ICS, and must ``preempt inconsistent
state regulations.'' Additional commenters echo these assertions,
arguing that the Commission has jurisdiction over both interstate and
intrastate rates and must preempt inconsistent state requirements.
Indeed, the Wright Petitioners state that ``there is no debate that the
FCC has the authority to preempt those state regulations that conflict
with regulations adopted in this proceeding.''
208. Other commenters contend that the Commission lacks the
authority to preempt state ICS requirements. According to the Arizona
Corporation Commission (ACC), for example, ``[s]ection 276 must be read
in pari materia with 47 U.S.C. 152's reservation of authority over
intrastate matters.'' The ACC further asserts that ``the primary
purpose of section 276 was to prevent unfair competition by incumbent
local exchange carriers against the payphone providers [and t]he other
express purpose of this section was to ensure that payphone providers
were fairly compensated for all calls placed using their payphones.''
In addition, the ACC claims that state regulation of intrastate ICS is
part of the states' ``historic police powers'' and therefore should not
be preempted unless preemption ``was the clear and manifest purpose of
Congress.''
2. Discussion
209. NARUC and the ACC argue that our authority under section 276
is limited to interstate services, and that our regulations must be
narrowly targeted to address concerns about anticompetitive conduct by
incumbent local exchange carriers. We disagree. These arguments are
contradicted by the plain language of section 276. As explained above,
the statute provides the Commission with the authority to regulate both
interstate and intrastate ICS. Similarly, although section 276
addresses potential discrimination by Bell operating companies, it also
contains provisions related to other subjects, including compensation
for ``payphone service providers,'' a group that, by definition,
encompasses providers ``of inmate telephone service in correctional
institutions, and any ancillary services.'' Furthermore, we believe
that section 276's broad mandate stands in stark opposition to ACC's
and NARUC's attempts to narrowly confine the Commission's ICS-related
preemption authority.
210. Pay Tel urges the Commission to preempt state-imposed
intrastate rates that are below the adopted caps, arguing that any
rates that deviate from the Commission's caps are ``by definition,
`inconsistent''' and must be preempted. We disagree. The primary
purpose of the rate caps we adopt today is to ensure that ICS rates are
``just and reasonable'' and do not take unfair advantage of inmates or
their families. State requirements that result in rates below our caps
advance that purpose and there is no credible record evidence
demonstrating or indicating that any requirements that result in rates
below our conservative caps are so low as to clearly deny providers
fair compensation. Evidence in the record shows that ICS can be
provided at rates at or below $0.05 a minute. We applaud the efforts
some states have made to lower ICS rates and hope other states follow
their lead. Our goal is affordable rates that provide fair
compensation, and the federal framework we adopt today is meant to
serve as a backstop to ensure rates are consistent with the statute in
absence of state action.
211. We are mindful, however, of the fact that we also have a
statutory obligation to ensure that payphone service providers,
including ICS providers, are ``fairly compensated.'' If any state
adopts intrastate requirements that result in providers being unable to
receive fair compensation, providers may either seek appropriate relief
in that state or from the Commission. We will review the relevant state
requirements if they are brought to our attention in a petition and
will decide at that time what, if any, remedial actions are warranted.
If any party believes that a particular form of relief is called for,
that party should clearly state the requested relief in a petition and
set forth the legal authority for granting such relief. As noted above,
section 276 explicitly grants the Commission authority to preempt state
requirements to the extent they are inconsistent with FCC regulations.
Accordingly, if a provider is able to demonstrate that a particular
state law or requirement is inconsistent with the rules we adopt in
this Order, we will, consistent with section 276, preempt the
inconsistent requirement. We strongly encourage providers to seek
relief from the relevant state entity before approaching the
Commission, however. We also note that there is no presumption that
state-mandated rates deny fair compensation simply because they are
lower than our rate caps. To the contrary, as noted above, we encourage
states to enact additional reforms to inmate calling service and to
drive intrastate rates as low as possible, consistent with the need to
ensure fair compensation, retain service quality, and maintain adequate
security.
212. Consistent with the regulatory approach adopted herein,
providers may be able to comply with such statutory requirements
without charging rates that exceed our rate caps. Given the absence of
clear evidence indicating whether there are any state laws or other
requirements that, in practice, would require providers to charge rates
that exceed our caps, we need not decide whether any laws currently
exist that are ``inconsistent'' with our regulatory framework. To the
extent there are state requirements, including possible contractual
requirements, that make our rate caps onerous for a particular
provider, the affected provider may file for preemption of the state
requirement or seek a temporary waiver of the rate caps for the
duration of any existing contract. We note that any waiver request
should include a discussion of the provider's efforts to renegotiate
the subject contracts and the outcome of such efforts. We delegate to
the Bureau the authority to rule on such petitions and to seek
additional information as needed. We also direct the Bureau to endeavor
to complete review of any such petitions within 90 days of the provider
submitting all information necessary to justify a waiver.
3. Existing Contracts
213. As the Commission has previously noted, ICS contracts
``typically include change of law provisions.'' We expect that the new
rate caps and other requirements adopted in this Order constitute
regulatory changes sufficient to trigger contractual change-in-law
provisions that will allow ICS providers to void, modify or renegotiate
aspects of their existing contracts to the extent necessary to comply
with the new rate caps and/or to relieve the providers from site
commission payments that would prove to be unduly onerous once this
Order takes effect. The record regarding implementation of the 2013
interim rate caps indicates that such changes were implemented quickly.
Indeed, the Commission has previously highlighted the fact that the
record ``indicates that ICS contracts are amended on a regular basis.''
For
[[Page 79165]]
instance, the record indicates that Securus provided nine days' notice
to facilities prior to implementing the rate caps adopted in the 2013
Order. The record also indicates that GTL had a four-day transition
period after executing a new contract to serve the state of Ohio.
214. Parties have further argued that invoking contractual change
of law provisions and engaging in renegotiations with correctional
facilities would materially affect ICS providers' ability to conduct
their daily business. Yet the Commission saw little such impact
regarding implementation of the 2013 interim rate caps. Those rate caps
affected all interstate calls throughout the country, much like today's
reforms will affect calls nationwide. Our experience with the
Commission's previous reforms leads us to conclude that, for ICS
providers that choose to invoke existing change of law provisions--and
subsequently to engage in renegotiations with the facilities they
serve--any inconvenience imposed on them in doing so will not
materially affect the providers' ability to conduct their day-to-day
business. Finally, the negotiations for any new or renewed contracts
can and should be informed by the decisions in this Order, including
our adoption of new rate caps for ICS.
215. ICS providers that have entered into contracts without change-
of-law provisions did so with full knowledge that the Commission's ICS
proceeding has been pending since 2012. Even so, we encourage
facilities to work with those ICS providers during the transition
period described below which we believe provides ample time to
renegotiate contracts, if necessary, to be consistent with this Order.
If any provider believes it is being denied fair compensation during
the transition or implementation of the reforms adopted in this Order--
due, for example, to the interaction of our rate caps with the terms of
the provider's existing service contracts--it may file a petition
seeking a limited waiver of our new rate caps or seek preemption of the
requirement to pay a site commission, to the extent that it believes
that such a requirement is a state requirement and is inconsistent with
the Commission's regulations. Finally, negotiations for any new or
renewed contracts can and should comply with the decisions in this
Order, including our limitation on site commission payments and our
adoption of new rate caps.
216. We note that the contractual provisions to which a state
subjects itself, or its subdivision, may reasonably be subsumed within
the ``state requirements'' addressed by section 276(c). Therefore, if a
state or a political subdivision thereof uses a contractual agreement
as a vehicle to impose certain requirements regarding rates or other
aspects of ICS, we would consider, on a case-by-case, fact-specific
basis, preempting those requirements to the extent they are
``inconsistent with the Commission's regulations'' as set forth in this
Order. Without deciding whether preemption is factually or legally
warranted in any particular case, we note that a contrary
interpretation could leave states and localities free to undermine the
Commission's implementation of section 276 by doing so via a contract,
rather than a state law or regulation, which result appears to be
counter to Congress's objectives in enacting section 276(c). As the
Commission has noted in this very proceeding, ``agreements cannot
supersede the Commission's authority to ensure that the rates paid by
individuals who are not parties to those agreements are fair, just and
reasonable.'' To the extent ICS providers require waiver relief, they
may take advantage of the procedures described below.
F. Waivers of Rules Adopted in This Order
217. In the 2013 Order, the Commission held that an ICS provider
that ``believes that it has cost-based rates for ICS that exceed our
interim rate caps'' may file a petition for waiver for good cause. The
2013 Order also confirmed that the Commission's standard waiver process
applies to ICS providers. The Commission delegated to the Bureau the
authority to approve or deny waiver requests. The Commission
articulated the following factors that the Bureau could consider in
reviewing a waiver request: Costs directly related to the provision of
interstate ICS and ancillary services; demand levels and trends; a
reasonable allocation of common costs; and general and administrative
cost data. The Commission also noted that, because the adopted interim
interstate rate caps were set at conservative levels, it expected that
petitions for waiver ``would account for extraordinary circumstances.''
Additionally, the Commission held that, for ``substantive and
administrative reasons,'' waiver petitions would be evaluated at the
holding company level. The Bureau processed three requests for waiver
of the interim interstate rate caps following this guidance and granted
a temporary waiver to one provider.
218. In the Second FNPRM, the Commission sought comment on the
waiver process detailed in the 2013 Order. Several commenters object to
the use of this waiver process to address concerns about the
sufficiency of the rate caps. Some ICS providers ask that we review
waiver petitions on a facility-by-facility basis in order to review
locations where the costs of service exceed the rate caps. One
commenter requests an expedited waiver process to allow the adoption of
products or services involving costs paid to a third party, such as
those involving a software agreement or new security feature.
Commenters also suggest that the Bureau issue a blanket waiver
excluding juvenile detention centers, secure mental health facilities,
and jails with small populations, from our rate caps.
219. We have relied on the Mandatory Data Collection in
establishing the rate caps adopted above. For the reasons previously
given, we believe our rate caps are more than sufficient to allow
carriers to receive fair compensation. We agree with the Petitioners
that a tiered rate cap approach, as adopted herein, will reduce the
need for waivers. We recognize, however, that we cannot foreclose the
possibility that in certain limited instances, our rate caps may not be
sufficient for certain providers. For those instances, we reaffirm the
waiver standard for ICS providers adopted in the 2013 Order and
delegate to the Bureau the authority to rule on such waivers.
Accordingly, an ICS provider that believes the rate caps for interstate
and intrastate ICS do not allow for fair compensation may seek a waiver
pursuant to the guidance articulated in the 2013 Order. ICS provider
waiver petitions may be accorded confidential treatment to the extent
consistent with rule 0.459. We direct the Bureau to endeavor act to on
such waivers within 90 days of the provider submitting all information
necessary to justify a waiver. As the Commission previously stated,
waiver petitions should be filed at the holding-company level. We
believe that this approach best captures the way the majority of the
ICS market functions; specifically that ICS providers serve multiple
facilities utilizing centralized infrastructure, thus spreading related
costs across their correctional facility customer base whenever
possible. Furthermore, as described in the 2013 Order, providers will
be expected to provide data showing why they are unable to meet their
costs under the applicable rate caps. We reiterate that ``unless and
until a waiver is granted, an ICS provider may not charge rates above
the [applicable] rate cap and must comply with all aspects of this
Order . . . .'' However, consistent with Commission precedent,
[[Page 79166]]
exigent circumstances may warrant that the Bureau provide interim
relief during the pendency of its review of a waiver request.
220. We also conclude that there is insufficient evidence available
at this time to support a blanket waiver to providers incurring third-
party technology costs or serving high-cost facilities. The Bureau will
consider waiver petitions, including those from providers claiming to
serve high-cost facilities, and evaluate the details specific to such
petitions on a case-by-case basis.
G. Disability Access to ICS
1. Background
221. In the 2012 NPRM, the Commission noted that ``there is
evidence in the record to indicate that inmates with hearing
disabilities may not have access to ICS at reasonable rates using TTYs
[text telephones].'' Specifically, the Commission cited evidence that
``deaf and hard of hearing inmates who use TTYs have to pay more than
their hearing counterparts'' because ``the average length of a
telephone conversation using a TTY is approximately four times longer
than a voice telephone conversation.'' In light of this record, the
Commission sought comment about the ICS access available to deaf and
hard of hearing inmates and about the rates such inmates paid for ICS.
222. In the 2013 Order, the Commission clarified that ICS providers
may not collect additional charges for calls made through any type of
telecommunications relay service (TRS). In the Second FNPRM that
accompanied the 2013 Order, the Commission also noted commenters'
assertions that TTY calls take ``at least three to four times longer
than voice-to-voice conversations to deliver the same conversational
content.'' The Commission, therefore, tentatively concluded that per-
minute ICS rates for TTY calls should be 25 percent of the rate for
standard ICS calls, and sought comment on this proposal. In addition,
the Commission sought comment on a number of other issues related to
ICS for inmates who are deaf and hard of hearing, including: (1)
Whether and how to discount the per-minute rate for ICS calls placed
using TTY; (2) whether action is required to ensure that ICS providers
do not deny access to TRS by blocking calls to 711 and/or state
established TRS access numbers; (3) the need for ICS providers to
receive complaints on TRS and file reports on those complaints with the
Commission; and (4) actions the Commission can take to promote the
availability and use of video relay service (VRS) and other assistive
technologies in prisons.
223. The Commission asked additional questions about accessible ICS
in the Second FNPRM. Specifically, the Commission sought comment on the
following: (1) The actual relative length of TTY-to-TTY and TTY-to-
voice calls as compared to voice-to-voice calls; (2) the claim that no
ICS provider charges for voice-to-TTY or TTY-to-voice calls because
``the `interexchange company holding the [state] TRS contract carries
the call to the called party,' '' and if true, whether the final
reduced ICS rates for TTY calls should only apply to TTY-to-TTY calls;
(3) whether AT&T and other entities that provide TRS are providing ICS
for TRS calls placed by inmates; (4) how the Commission's relay service
registration requirements can be met in a correctional facility setting
where the equipment is handled by several users; and (5) the
availability of and security concerns relating to devices used with
newer technologies, such as videophones used for VRS and point-to-point
video communications, devices used for IP CTS, and devices used for IP
Relay.
224. Since 2012, when the Commission first sought comment on access
to ICS for inmates who are deaf or hard of hearing, the Commission has
continued to receive filings expressing concern about these prisoners'
lack of access to telephone services that are functionally equivalent
to the services available to users of traditional voice services. The
Washington Lawyers' Committee (WLC), for example, claims that
correctional facilities often fail to make TRS available to inmates.
Similarly, Helping Educate to Advance the Rights of the Deaf (HEARD)
asserts that ``deaf prisoners in several states have had no
telecommunications access for several years, while deaf detainees often
spend their entire time in jail with no telecommunication.'' According
to the Rosen Bien Galvan & Grunfeld (RBGG) law firm, its clients
``routinely report that their access even to outdated and disfavored
[TTYs], particularly in county jail facilities, is limited to
nonexistent and that their ability to communicate with loved ones and
attorneys is thereby impaired.'' RBGG further asserts that, even when
correctional facilities have TTYs, ``they are often not actually
available to our clients because they are broken, because staff does
not know they exist, or because staff does not know how to use the
machines.''
225. In response to the Second FNPRM, Securus and GTL contend that
correctional facilities, not the ICS providers, ``set correction
facility policy as to the amount of access that hearing-impaired
inmates (or any inmates) have to telecommunications services.'' GTL
also asserts that ``disability access concerns are being addressed by
the industry'' and that GTL's inmate calling services and the rates for
those services are ``fully compliant with the requirements of the
Americans with Disabilities Act (ADA), the Communications Act of 1934,
as amended, and current Commission requirements.''
2. Discussion
226. Functionally Equivalent Access. We now take measures to
address the various concerns and ongoing reports regarding the lack of
equal telephone access by inmates. As an initial matter, we note that
this proceeding has generally referred to individuals who are ``deaf
and hard of hearing,'' in discussing accessibility matters. Because
inmates who are deaf-blind or have speech disabilities also use TRS,
they, too, have the same or similar policy concerns as inmates who are
deaf or hard of hearing. Accordingly, we will now refer more generally
to inmates with ``communication disabilities'' when discussing these
accessibility issues. Additionally, we note that while our focus here
is primarily on calls that are made by inmates with these disabilities,
some of the policies we adopt requiring access to TRS will also benefit
inmates who need to place calls to people with such disabilities.
227. Section 225 of the Act requires every common carrier that
provides voice services to offer access to TRS within their service
areas. Accordingly, all common carriers must make available, or ensure
the availability, to their customers of those types of TRS that the
Commission has required to be mandatory services provided to the
public. At present, the Commission mandates two forms of TRS: TTY-based
TRS and speech-to-speech (STS), both of which are provided over the
PSTN. We remind ICS providers of their obligations to ensure the
availability and provision of these forms of TRS. Consistent with these
obligations, ICS providers also may not block calls to 711, a short
form dialing code that is used to access TRS provided by state-run TRS
programs.
228. We note that several parties have requested that the
Commission require correctional facilities to provide more ``modern''
forms of TRS as well, along with the equipment needed to access those
services. These parties assert that TTYs are largely outdated and that
videophones and captioned telephones
[[Page 79167]]
are the standard modes of communication for people with communication
disabilities. For example, RBGG urges the Commission's ``active
intervention'' to encourage facilities to adopt modern communications
technologies, such as videophones. Similarly, the National Association
of the Deaf (NAD) asserts that ``correctional facilities should be
required to install and provide access to the telecommunications
equipment required by deaf and hard of hearing inmates--whether it's a
TTY, videophone, captioned telephone, or even an amplified telephone or
one that is amplified and has large buttons.''
229. The Communications Act requires TRS to be provided ``in a
manner that is functionally equivalent to the ability of a hearing
individual'' to use conventional voice telephone services. We agree
with commenters that limiting all inmates with communication
disabilities to one form of TRS, particularly what many view as an
outdated form of TRS that relies on TTY usage, may result in
communication that is not functionally equivalent to the ability of a
hearing individual to communicate by telephone. However, as noted
above, at this time, only two forms of TRS, TTY-based TRS and STS, are
mandated services for all common carriers. While the Commission
authorizes compensation from the Interstate TRS Fund for VRS, IP Relay,
and both PSTN-based CTS and IP CTS, it does not mandate that these
types of services be provided by any common carrier at this time.
Accordingly, while we are only able to require ICS providers to make
TTY-based TRS and STS available to inmates with communication
disabilities, or to inmates who communicate by telephone with users of
these services at this time, we strongly encourage correctional
facilities to work with ICS providers to offer these other forms of
TRS.
230. Several inmates with communications disabilities that have
commented in the record note that in some instances, using a
Telecommunication Device for the Deaf (TDD) is unsatisfactory because
``[o]ur family members and friends who are deaf, are no longer using
the obsolete TDD system.'' We reaffirm our existing policy of strongly
encouraging correctional facilities to provide inmates with
communication disabilities with access to TTYs, as well as equipment
used for advanced forms of TRS, such as videophones and captioned
telephones. In addition, we strongly encourage correctional facilities
to comply with obligations that may exist under other federal laws,
including Title II of the ADA, which require the provision of services
to inmates with disabilities that are as effective as those provided to
other inmates. Access to more advanced forms of TRS, including VRS, IP
Relay, CTS, and IP CTS, may be necessary to ensure equally effective
telephone services for these inmates. We recognize that some facilities
have already begun providing access to alternative forms of TRS, often
as the result of litigation brought under these other statutes. We
strongly encourage other facilities to continue this trend voluntarily,
without the need for further litigation. The Commission will monitor
the implementation and access to TRS in correctional institutions and
may take additional action if inmates with communications disabilities
continue to lack access to functionally equivalent service.
231. Rates. Several commenters have also expressed concern about
the costs inmates with communication disabilities incur when they use
TTYs. HEARD, for example, asserts that TTY calls are ``at least four
times slower than voice-to-voice conversations'' and that ``this time
estimation does not account for varied literacy levels of users;
`garbled' transmissions that frequently occur in loud settings or with
incompatible newer telephone technology; or the time required to
connect to the operator, and subsequently to the party being called,
among other things.'' One commenter describes his experience as an
inmate with communications disabilities:
[a]fter you give the relay operator your name for the collect call
the relay operator put[s] you back on hold once again to see if
charges will be accepted by the party at the other end of your call.
This process takes at least 5 to 8 minutes. This time is part of the
15-minute time limit that the Department of Corrections has on their
timers for each call. Now keep in mind that a regular call costs a
total of about $2 but the relay service had a $3.62 hook up fee,
then so much per minute after that so you only get 5 to 7 min. and
you have to call back and repeat this process.
232. Given the differences between TTY and traditional voice
service, several commenters argue that TTY users should be charged a
discounted rate for ICS calls. The Prison Law Office, for example, has
argued that if the Commission does not take into account the relatively
slow speeds of TTY-based conversations, it will be ``in effect placing
a surcharge on deaf prisoners.'' The Commission itself tentatively
concluded in the 2013 Order that the per-minute ICS rate for TTY calls
should be set at 25 percent of the safe harbor rate of $0.12/minute for
debit/prepaid calls and $0.14/minute for collect calls.
233. Neither ICS providers, nor any other commenters, dispute
arguments that TTY calls are longer, and therefore more expensive to
consumers than non-TTY calls. Instead, Securus merely contends that it
receives no additional compensation for this type of call above its
tariffed rate. GTL, for its part, generally asserts that its ICS and
associated rates are ``fully compliant with the requirements of the
Americans with Disabilities Act, the Communications Act of 1934, as
amended, and current Commission requirements.''
234. We find that the record overwhelmingly supports the conclusion
that TTY calls take significantly longer than voice conversations, due
to factors that include the longer time it takes the TTY user to type--
rather than speak--his or her part of the conversation; the time delays
that occur while the text is transmitted; and the technical
difficulties that appear to affect TTY calls disproportionately
compared to voice calls. TTY calls through TRS can take even longer
than calls between two TTY users, because of the need for such calls to
be set up before the communications assistant can connect the TTY user
to the voice telephone user, and the need for the communications
assistant to transcribe the spoken part of the call and relay it to the
TTY user.
235. Given that there does not appear to be any dispute in the
record over whether TTY calls take longer to transact than voice calls
involving similar content, the question remains whether inmates with
communication disabilities (or their families) should be required to
pay more for ICS calls than their hearing counterparts simply because
they need to rely on TTYs to communicate with their friends and
relatives. As explained below, we find that it would be unfairly
discriminatory to require TTY users to pay more per call than users of
traditional voice telephone equipment.
236. In the 2013 Order, the Commission clarified that it would be
inconsistent with section 225 of the Act for ICS providers to collect
``additional charges'' (i.e., charges in excess of those charged by the
ICS provider for functionally equivalent voice communications service)
for calls made through any type of telecommunications relay service.
The 2013 Order, however, did not address the relevance of section 276
to ICS provider charges for TRS calls. Section 276, which requires the
Commission to ensure that ICS
[[Page 79168]]
providers ``are fairly compensated for each and every completed
intrastate and interstate call,'' also states that TRS calls ``shall
not be subject to such compensation.'' Thus, we believe it is
reasonable for the Commission to interpret 276(b)(1)(A) to mean that
TRS calls are not subject to the per-call compensation framework
adopted herein. Specifically, section 276 exempts both emergency calls
and TRS calls from the fair compensation mandate. The exemption of
emergency calls means that providers may not charge for emergency
calls. We believe it is reasonable to interpret the pairing of TRS with
emergency calls as an indication that Congress also intended TRS calls
be provided for no charge. Therefore, we prohibit ICS providers from
assessing charges for ICS calls between a TTY device and a traditional
telephone.
237. As for TTY-to-TTY calls, we find that, because such calls, by
their nature, are of longer duration than voice calls, and because
inmates with communication disabilities do not have the alternative of
placing voice calls, it would be unfairly discriminatory to require TTY
users to pay more per call than users of traditional voice telephone
equipment. This finding is compelled not only by the evidence in the
record, but also by the language of the relevant statutory provision.
Section 276 requires the Commission to establish a ``per call
compensation plan'' to ensure that payphone providers, including ICS
providers, are fairly compensated for ``each and every . . . call.''
Such per-call compensation must be ``fair'' not only to the provider
but also to the party paying for the call. Because of the significantly
longer time that is necessarily consumed by TTY calls--as compared to
the duration of voice telephone ICS calls--we conclude that, to ensure
fair compensation on a per-call basis, ICS providers should offer TTY
calls at lower per-minute rates than are charged for voice calls, even
if such lower rates do not provide the level of per-minute compensation
determined to be fair for voice telephone calls in the ``per call
compensation plan.'' We reach this decision because of the per-call
discrimination that would result were we to set the same rates for both
types of calls.
238. Accordingly, for the reasons described above, we require that
the rates charged by ICS providers for TTY-to-TTY calls be no more than
25 percent of the rates the providers charge for traditional inmate
calling services. We recognize that this discounted rate may not
represent the same level of compensation that is provided for voice
telephone calls carried over the same networks, but we have considered
any additional costs that might be incurred by providers in setting the
rate caps for ICS and concluded that there is enough room within the
general rate caps to ensure the providers are still fairly compensated.
Thus, ICS providers can expect to recover the cost of the TTY discount
through the rates they charge other users, who account for the vast
majority of ICS calls.
239. In setting the mandatory discount for ICS calls involving
TTYs, we are cognizant of Securus' claim that it cannot track TTY calls
separately from other ICS calls and that any type of TRS-related
billing requirement ``would be extremely time-consuming and
burdensome.'' If Securus, or any other ICS provider, finds it too
burdensome to track TTY calls and bill customers the discounted rate
for those calls, it may opt to provide TTY-to-TTY calling for free. We
expect the cost of forgoing the discounted fees for the relatively
small number of TTY users of ICS will be nominal and that providers
will be able to recover those costs through the ``cushion'' we have
built into our rate caps. We find that the benefit to inmates that use
TTY and TRS technologies outweighs any nominal costs to ICS providers.
Finally, we note that facilities and ICS providers can avoid costs
related to TRS calls by allowing inmates to use IP-based forms of TRS,
such as VRS, IP Relay and IP CTS. However, the record indicates that
``only a handful of prisons are equipped with videophones (e.g.,
Vermont, Virginia, and Wisconsin) and no prison or jail is known to
have installed captioned telephones, many using security as an excuse
for discrimination.'' These calls would not require the services of an
ICS provider and would be provided free of charge to both the user and
to the facility.
240. Disability-Access Related Reporting. In discussing ICS
disability access issues in the 2013 Order, the Commission asked
whether ICS providers should be required to collect and report: ``(i)
Data on TRS usage via ICS, and (ii) complaints from individuals that
access TRS via ICS.'' The Commission also sought comment ``on the
benefits and burdens, including on small entities, of imposing these
reporting requirements.''
241. In the Second FNPRM, the Commission again sought comment on
possible recordkeeping and reporting requirements specific to
accessible ICS. Specifically, the Commission asked if ``ICS providers
[should] be required to report to the Commission the number of
disability-related calls they provide, the number of problems they
experience with such calls, or related complaints they receive?'' In
response, the NAD asserts that the Commission should require
``complaints, technical problems, how much telecommunications access is
provided as compared to non-deaf or hard of hearing inmates, and
whether there is access to modern telecommunications equipment.'' HEARD
asserts that ``[t]he Commission can generate a genuine sense of
accountability simply by requiring ICS providers to collect and report
data on calls made using relay service, especially if prisoners and
family members are paying for the service.'' More specifically, HEARD
suggests that, pursuant to the Commission's existing consumer complaint
procedures, correctional facilities should be required to report how
long they have been without relay service or access, and if a recent
change in the ICS provider preceded the problem.
242. Securus counters that ``tracking of TTY is not possible'' and
that culling out calls would require Securus ``to write a new computer
application for its billing system'' and ``establish `separate
databases at each correctional facility to identify inmates that may
use a TTY device or call friends or family that require the use of a
TTY or similar device.' '' Securus further asserts that this difficulty
is ``compounded for any facility that does not use Prison
Identification Numbers in association with its inmate telephone
system.'' Securus asserts generally that any type of TRS-related
billing or call recordkeeping requirement ``would be extremely time-
consuming and burdensome.''
243. GTL separately asserts that the new technologies it is
introducing, which are ``better categorized as advanced communications
services (ACS), enhanced services, or simply new technologies'' are
already subject to certain disability access requirements, including
recordkeeping and reporting requirements. GTL is specifically referring
to rule 14.31, which requires ACS providers discontinuing a product or
service to create and keep records (for a two year period) relating to:
(1) Their efforts to consult with individuals with disabilities; (2)
the accessibility features of their products and services; and (3) the
compatibility of their products and services with peripheral devices or
specialized customer premise equipment commonly used to help
individuals with disabilities achieve access. Additionally, ACS
providers must file an annual compliance certificate with the
Commission.
[[Page 79169]]
Finally, ACS providers facing formal or informal accessibility
complaints must produce responsive records to the Commission upon
request.
244. After reviewing the record, we adopt the reporting
requirements proposed by HEARD and supported by NAD. Specifically, we
require all ICS providers to include in the Annual Reporting and
Certification filing described below: (1) The number of disability-
related calls they provided; (2) the number of dropped disability-
related calls they experienced; and (3) the number of complaints they
received related to access to ICS by TTY and TRS users, e.g., dropped
calls, poor call quality and the number of incidences of each. We agree
with HEARD that these reporting requirements will foster accountability
on the part of ICS providers. We believe these reporting requirements
will encourage providers to actively address problems affecting users'
ability to access TRS (including TTY) via ICS. Moreover, the reports
will give the Commission the information needed to assess ICS
providers' compliance with the requirements adopted herein, as well as
those imposed by section 225, including the statutory requirement that
individuals with communications disabilities must be able to engage in
communication by wire or radio ``in a manner that is functionally
equivalent to the ability of a hearing individual who does not have a
speech disability,'' as well as the requirement that TRS be provided
``in the most efficient manner.''
245. Securus' main objection to the reporting requirements appears
to be related solely to the difficulty of tracking TRS calls. But the
record indicates that TRS calls make up only a small portion of ICS
calls. Moreover, TTY-based TRS calls require specialized equipment and/
or require calling a designated number such as 711. Either scenario
should facilitate tracking TTY-based TRS calls. For instance, it should
not be difficult to track a relatively small number of calls made from
specialized equipment located in a correctional facility. Moreover, any
burdens associated with providing limited reporting on these calls are
far outweighed by the benefits such reporting will offer in terms of
greater transparency and heightened accountability on the part of ICS
providers. For example, our reporting requirements will facilitate
monitoring of issues related to TRS calls, encourage greater engagement
by the advocacy community, and provide the Commission the basis to take
further action, if necessary, to improve inmates' access to TRS.
246. We further address concerns regarding the burdensomeness of
our reporting requirements by establishing a safe harbor that will
allow ICS providers to avoid any reporting obligations if certain
conditions are met. Specifically, if an ICS provider either (1)
operates in a facility that allows the offering of additional forms of
TRS beyond those we currently mandate or (2) has not received any
complaints related to TRS calls, then it will not have to include any
TRS-related reporting in the Annual Report detailed below, provided
that it includes a certification from an officer of the company stating
which prong(s) of the safe harbor it has met. If the facility an ICS
provider serves either ceases allowing additional forms of TRS beyond
those we mandate or the ICS provider begins to receive TRS-related
complaints, however, it must include all required TRS reporting
information in its next Annual Report. We note that a report that
includes the number of TRS calls provides important context for
determining whether the number of complaints or dropped calls reported
by a provider is problematic. We believe that allowing these safe
harbors will provide equal or superior benefits over the reporting
requirements because if taken advantage of they help mitigate ICS
providers' concerns over the burdens associated with reporting
(although we believe these burdens are minimal), and will help drive
the adoption of more modern forms of TRS by correctional facilities,
which helps further the deployment of ICS as well as helps maintain or
increase contact between more incarcerated persons and the outside
world.
247. Cost-Benefit Analysis. We find that the reporting and
recordkeeping requirements related to disability-access ICS calling
adopted in this Order are not overly burdensome. Parties have
complained that the disability access communications within
correctional facilities are not priced at rates that are just,
reasonable, and fair, and that Commission intervention is necessary.
248. As discussed above, we conclude that these recordkeeping
requirements are necessary to foster accountability on the part of ICS
providers, and will encourage providers to address problems limiting
users' ability to access TRS (including TTY) via ICS. Further, the
reporting requirements will give us the information we need to assess
ICS providers' compliance with the requirements adopted herein, as well
as those imposed by section 225.
249. We find unpersuasive the objections raised to the reporting
requirements. Reporting the number of problems and complaints
associated with TRS calls does not seem unduly burdensome. TRS calls
make up only a small portion of ICS calls. Moreover, as noted above,
TTY-based calls require specialized equipment and/or require calls to a
designated number, such as 711; either scenario should allow for ease
of tracking. Moreover, any burdens associated with providing limited
reporting on these calls are far outweighed by the benefits such
reporting will offer in terms of greater transparency and heightened
accountability on the part of ICS providers. We further mitigate any
potential burden from our reporting requirements by establishing safe
harbors that allow ICS providers to avoid any reporting obligations if
certain conditions are met, as discussed more fully above.
H. Section 276 Is Technology Neutral
250. We confirm the findings in the 2013 Order that section 276, by
its terms, is technology neutral with respect to inmate calling
services. As such, our rules adopted herein apply to ICS regardless of
the technology used to deliver the service. Therefore, if a particular
service meets the relevant definition in our rules, then it is a form
of ICS that was subject to our interim rules and that is subject to the
rules we adopt today. The nomenclature used to describe a service is
not dispositive of whether the service is or is not ICS. Whether any
particular service meets those definitions requires a fact-specific
inquiry that we may adjudicate if necessary. (We note that our
definition of ``inmate telephone'' is broad and does not inherently
rule out advanced services, and that the burden is on the provider in
the first instance to determine whether it is providing ICS, and if it
is not certain, to seek guidance from the Commission, for example in
the form of a Declaratory Ruling.)
I. Transition and Existing Contracts
251. In establishing the transition, we balance the critical goal
of providing necessary relief to consumers from unreasonably high ICS
rates while remaining mindful of the potential impact on ICS providers
and facilities to ensure a smooth transition to implement the new
reforms. In designing our transition for this Order, we build on the
lessons learned from implementing the 2013 ICS reforms. The record does
not indicate that providers experienced difficulties implementing the
rate caps within 90 days after the 2013 Order's publication in the
Federal Register. For example, the record shows that one provider sent
a one-page letter to its customers informing them of the rate
[[Page 79170]]
changes to be implemented as a result of the Commission's 2013 Order.
The letter provided nine days' notice before rates changed. While we
find that a multi-year transition period for new rate caps is
unnecessary, we recognize that the new rate caps and ancillary service
charge framework adopted in this Order may require some adjustment time
for ICS providers and facilities. Accordingly, the reforms adopted in
this Order will become effective March 17, 2016 for prisons and June
20, 2016 for jails.
252. This transition period reflects a careful balancing of the
important goal of expediting relief to end users while allowing the
necessary time to prepare for any impact our new rules may have on ICS
providers and correctional institutions. In adopting the transition, we
note as a threshold matter that the issue of ICS reform has been
pending for years and, with the substantial progress made in recent
years through the 2013 Order and Second FNPRM, ICS providers and
facilities have been on notice that the Commission may reform ICS. With
that consideration in mind, we transition to our new rules March 17,
2016 for prisons and June 20, 2016 for jails. Below we also discuss the
effect of our adopted reforms on existing ICS contracts.
1. Transition Proposals in the Record
253. In the Second FNPRM, the Commission sought comment on a
variety of transition paths for the new rules and encouraged commenters
advocating for a transition to identify the appropriate transition
framework and the justifications for doing so. For example, the ICS
providers that submitted the Joint Provider Proposal suggested that
``[t]he new rate caps should become effective 90 days after adoption,
along with any site commission reductions and ancillary fee changes
outlined below.'' They further asserted that ``[t]his period for
implementation should ensure ICS providers and correctional facilities
have adequate time to implement the new rate caps and any corresponding
reductions in site commissions, including any contract amendments or
adjustments that may be necessary.'' Pay Tel suggested a 90-day, after
final order publication transition period for transaction fees, third-
party money transfer service fees, and ancillary fees and an 18-month
transition period for jail and prison rate caps. In the Second FNPRM
the Commission also specifically sought comment on the 90-day delayed
effective date we implemented in the 2013 Order as well as a two year
transition.
254. In response to the Second FNPRM, many interested parties
submitted detailed comments explaining how the Commission should
structure the transition to new rules for ICS rates. Commenters
advocated for a variety of transition period lengths and the responses
varied depending on the type of fee being transitioned. Some commenters
suggested that all of the new rate caps, ancillary service charges, and
other charges should be transitioned together. For example, GTL
explained that ``[i]t is unlikely that the Commission's goal of
achieving market-based ICS rates will occur without simultaneous
Commission action to establish backstop rate caps for all ICS rates, to
transition site commissions to admin-support payments, and to define
industry-wide ancillary service charges and fee caps.'' We took such
arguments into consideration in designing our transition.
255. At the other end of the spectrum, commenters advocating for a
longer transition contend that longer transitions are necessary to
ensure that correctional authorities and ICS providers can plan for the
new regulatory regime. As discussed above, facilities have received
certain inducements, such as site commissions, from ICS providers for
selecting them to be the sole provider of ICS in their facilities.
These commissions have been used for a variety of purposes, some of
which are wholly unrelated to the provision of ICS to inmates and their
families. We acknowledge that our adopted rules and requirements may
affect facility budgets, and we want to ensure that those facilities
have time to account for disturbances to their budgets, which is why we
are not adopting an immediate transition.
256. Proponents of the shorter length transitions note that ICS
providers and facilities have been on notice of upcoming changes and
have successfully adjusted quickly to new rules in the past. For
example, NJAID and NYU IRC explain that ``[i]n New Jersey and around
the country, states and localities were able to implement the 2013
Order within ninety days. Moreover, these governments have been on
notice since the issuance of the First FNPRM in 2013.'' Commenters
advocating for shorter length transitions expressed confidence that 90
days was sufficient time to implement caps and would be the timeliest
option. Indeed, some parties argued that no more than 60 days are
necessary to complete the transition. Conversely, others worry that
abbreviated transitions, such as 90-day transitions, will not be
feasible for facilities to implement. However, other commenters point
out that ``[a]lmost every ICS contract has a provision for
renegotiation due to changes in the regulatory environment, so no one
year grace period should be required for implementation of rates and
fees.'' CenturyLink is concerned that a 90-day transition is not
``realistic,'' and advocates for a substantially longer transition
period. NSA argues that a 90-day transition is not sufficient for
jails, in particular. NSA notes that the sheer number of contracts to
be renegotiated would require additional time to complete, specifically
noting that there are ``over 2000 jails in the country and only a
``handful of ICS providers.'' Thus, NSA explains, each ICS provider
would have to renegotiate ``potentially hundreds of contracts with
Sheriffs and jails in a 90-day period.'' According to NSA, 90 days is
not enough time to allow providers to negotiate all of these contracts
and for those contracts to be approved by the relevant authorities.
These concerns are echoed by Praeses and others. We agree that these
parties raise valid concerns regarding the time needed to transition
all of the country's jails to the new rate regime. Accordingly, we
adopt a six-month transition period for jails, in order to give
providers and jails enough time to negotiate (or renegotiate) contracts
to the extent necessary to comply with all of the rules adopted herein.
We do not believe an extended transition is necessary for prisons to
obtain new or revised contracts, however. There are far fewer prisons/
departments of correction than jails (typically one per state) and
providers are likely to prioritize negotiations with prisons over
negotiations with jails, particularly given that prisons tend to house
much larger inmate populations and generate significantly more ICS
revenues than jails. Moreover, according to the record more than 10
prison systems already have rates at or below our rate caps. Therefore,
we adopt a 90-day transition period for prisons.
2. Implementation of Reforms and Transition Periods
257. The record reflects commenters advocating for immediate
transitions and also for transition periods ranging from 90 days to up
to three or four years. We find the arguments for a shorter transition
period to be the most persuasive. The immediate transition and long
transition options are impractical. For example, proponents of an
immediate transition generally explained that longer transition periods
are not necessary and would only serve to delay relief from quickly
reaching inmates and their families. Despite such
[[Page 79171]]
arguments, we think that the reforms adopted in this Order warrant
providing some amount of time to ensure a smooth transition for end
users, providers, and facilities.
258. As explained above, the record clearly shows that charges for
ancillary services have increased since the 2013 Order. This highlights
that ICS providers have the incentive and ability to increase ancillary
service charges absent reform, which could have the effect of
frustrating the Commission's and Congress's policy goals by undermining
the rate caps we adopt. While we have received substantial comment in
the record about the challenges associated with transitioning for our
site commission action and rate caps, the record lacks explanation as
to why an immediate transition for ancillary service charges would be
burdensome for ICS providers. As such, we find that transitioning
ancillary service charges on March 17, 2016 for prisons and June 20,
2016 for jails is appropriate because it will provide significant
relief to many ICS end users, while still giving providers ample time
to adjust their systems and procedures.
259. As explained above, our goal is to ensure a reasonable
transition and minimize disruption, while providing relief to end users
as quickly as possible. We have the benefit of understanding how the
transition to implement the interim interstate rate caps occurred.
Evidence in the record about actual transition periods calls into
question protestations in the record about the excessive time it will
take to renegotiate contracts, particularly for prisons. We adopt here
a 90-day transition from publication in the Federal Register for
prisons and six months from publication in the Federal Register for
jails for the adopted rate caps. We find that this length of time
adequately balances the pressing need for reform, affords ICS providers
enough time to prepare for the new rates, and is amply supported by the
record.
260. Evidence in the record indicates that some ICS providers and
their customers have been acting to modify contracts in an attempt to
lock in attractive terms at the expense of the ratepayers, the end
users, in anticipation of this Order. We are concerned that such
activity may also occur in between the adoption and effective dates of
this Order. We will be vigilant in monitoring the industry during the
transition period. If we observe or are made aware of evidence of price
gouging or other harmful behavior through, but not limited to,
increased rates, ancillary service charges, and/or site commissions, we
will not hesitate to take appropriate remedial action up to and
including enforcement action pursuant to our legal authority under
sections 201 and 276 or referral to another appropriate agency.
J. Anti-Gaming Provisions
261. We are concerned that parties may seek to negotiate agreements
aimed at circumventing the rules we adopt in this Order, and we are
particularly concerned that parties will have an incentive to do so
before our new rules take effect. To minimize this type of ``gaming,''
we prohibit ICS providers from entering into new contracts (including
contract renewals)--or negotiating amendments to existing contracts--
that would require or permit providers to charge rates in excess of our
adopted rate caps, impose ancillary service charges that are prohibited
by this Order, or charge ancillary service charges that exceed the caps
adopted in this Order. These prohibitions will take effect immediately
upon publication of the Order in the Federal Register.
262. We find that there is good cause to make this requirement
effective upon publication. There is evidence in the record that this
type of gaming has already occurred in anticipation of the changes we
enact in this Order. For example, a recent Securus contract requires
the payment of a $4 million minimum annual guarantee (MAG), which
advocates have called a ``signing bonus,'' and subsequent MAG payments
equal to the greater of $3.5 million or 81 percent of commissionable
revenues per year. In determining whether good cause exists, an agency
should ``balance the necessity for immediate implementation against
principles of fundamental fairness which require that all affected
persons be afforded a reasonable amount of time to prepare for the
effective date of its ruling.'' In this case, the rule must take effect
as soon as possible in order to minimize gaming of the sort already
noted in the record, and the attendant harm to prisoners and their
families in the form of unjust, unreasonable, and unfair rates and
fees. In these circumstances, we find that the need for immediate
implementation outweighs any concerns that parties may not be afforded
sufficient time to prepare for the effective date of this prohibition,
particularly given that parties have long been on notice that the
Commission might impose new regulations governing ICS rates and
ancillary fees. We are not requiring providers to take any action;
instead we are merely requiring that they refrain from taking certain
steps that would effectively undermine our regulations governing rates
and ancillary service charges. Accordingly, providers do not need time
to prepare to meet this prohibition. Therefore, on balance, we find
good cause to make this requirement effective upon publication in the
Federal Register.
K. Annual Reporting and Certification Requirement
263. In the 2013 Order, the Commission adopted an Annual Reporting
and Certification Requirement that included the submission of
interstate and intrastate ICS rate and demand data, as an additional
means of ensuring that each and every ICS provider's rates and
practices were just, reasonable, and fair, and remain in compliance
with the 2013 Order, as well as to facilitate any future enforcement
that may be needed regarding the adopted rules. Additionally, the
Commission adopted a requirement that an officer or director from each
ICS provider file an annual certification with the Commission as to the
accuracy of the data filed and as to the provider's compliance with all
portions of the adopted Order. These requirements were later stayed by
court order.
264. Recordkeeping and Reporting. The Joint Provider Proposal
suggests that ICS providers ``should be required to provide certain
information to the Commission annually for three (3) years to ensure
the caps on per-minute rates and any admin-support payments are
implemented as required.'' Specifically, the Proposal suggests that
such information should include four things: ``a list of the ICS
provider's current interstate and intrastate per-minute ICS rates, the
ICS provider's current fee amounts, the locations where the ICS
provider makes admin-support payments, and the amount of those admin-
support payments.'' The Commission sought comment on this proposal in
the Second FNPRM.
265. In its comments, CPC recommends that the Commission look to
the ``Alabama model,'' including the ``specific reporting requirements
that will serve to monitor compliance with those [adopted]
restrictions.'' In its 2014 Further Order Adopting Revised Inmate Phone
Service Rules Order, the Alabama PSC adopted a number of recordkeeping
and reporting requirements. Items to be recorded and reported annually
include, but are not limited, to, monthly number of local, intrastate,
and interstate calls; monthly local, intrastate, and interstate minutes
of use; monthly local, intrastate, and interstate call revenue, divided
into collect, prepaid collect, prepaid debit, prepaid inmate calling
card, and direct-billed service, divided by facility; ancillary call
charges;
[[Page 79172]]
unused prepaid collect, prepaid debit, and prepaid inmate phone card
account balances; and total number of calls disconnected for suspected
three-way call violations. That order was temporarily stayed by court
order which expired on July 1, 2015.
266. We find that a recordkeeping and reporting requirement will
best serve the Commission's stated goals of ensuring that each and
every ICS provider's rates and practices are just, reasonable, and
fair, and that they remain in compliance with this Order. We also
believe that an annual recordkeeping and reporting requirement will
help the Commission capture any trends or changes in calling patterns,
will facilitate any future enforcement action, and allow other
interested parties the ability to monitor ICS providers' compliance
with the Order. We also believe that such a requirement is necessary
because the ICS industry is modernizing and will continue to change.
Consistent with the Commission's approach in the 2013 Order, if after
an investigation it is determined that ICS providers rates and/or
ancillary service charges are unjust, unreasonable or unfair under
sections 201 and 276 of the Act, lower rates will be prescribed and ICS
providers may be ordered to pay refunds. Providers also may be found in
violation of our rules and face additional forfeitures.
267. We thus require all ICS providers to provide, on an annual
basis, categorized by facility and size of facility, the following
information: First, we require all ICS providers to file their current
interstate, international and intrastate ICS rates. Second, we require
all ICS providers to file their current ancillary service charge
amounts and the instances of use of each. Third, where an ICS provider
makes site commission payments, we require the ICS provider to file the
monthly amount of such payment. Fourth, for ICS providers that provided
video visitation services, either as a form of ICS or not, during the
reporting period, we require that they file the minutes of use and per-
minute rates and ancillary service charges for those services. Fifth,
as discussed in greater detail in the Disability Access section above,
we also require that ICS providers report: (1) The number of
disability-related calls they provided; (2) the number of problems they
experienced with such calls, e.g., dropped calls, poor call quality and
the number of incidences of each; and (3) the number of complaints they
received related to access to ICS by TTY and TRS users.
268. In order to facilitate compliance with this requirement, we
direct the Wireline Competition Bureau to develop a template for such
annual reports and provide for confidential treatment of any particular
information warranting it, consistent with our rules. We believe this
will help ensure that the incoming information is provided in the most
straight-forward and consistent manner. The use of such a template will
also be beneficial to any interested parties that want to view the
information thus encouraging increased public participation in this
proceeding. Each annual report shall be submitted to the Commission by
April 1st of each year, regarding the providers' interstate,
international and intrastate ICS. The first annual report will be due
after the Commission publishes Office of Management and Budget (OMB)
approval pursuant to the Ordering Clauses below. If for example, OMB
approval is granted in 2016 then the first annual report and
certification (as discussed below) will be due on April 1, 2017 and
cover the time period from January 1, 2016 to December 31, 2016.
269. Cost-Benefit Analysis. We find that a recordkeeping and
reporting requirement serves the Commission's goal of ensuring that ICS
rates and practices are just, reasonable, and fair, and that they
remain in compliance with this Order. We find, on balance, that the
benefits of such recordkeeping and reporting outweigh any potential
burden that may be imposed.
270. We find that such recordkeeping and reporting requirements
will help monitor ICS providers' compliance with the Order, capture any
trends or changes in calling patterns, and will facilitate any future
enforcement action. Such a requirement is necessary because the ICS
industry is modernizing and will continue to change.
271. We find very few objections raised to the reporting
requirements, and none to be persuasive. Additionally, we also find no
cost objections to these requirements. We have taken steps to minimize
burdens on providers by adopting less burdensome recordkeeping
requirements than some of those suggested by commenters. Moreover, any
burdens associated with providing limited reporting on these calls are
far outweighed by the benefits such reporting will offer in terms of
greater transparency and heightened accountability on the part of ICS
providers. Additionally, these data will guide the Commission as it
evaluates next steps in the Further Notice.
272. Annual Certification. The participants in the Joint Provider
Proposal suggest that all ICS providers should be required, in addition
to their recordkeeping and reporting requirements, to submit an annual
certification signed by the company Chief Executive Officer, Chief
Financial Officer, and General Counsel, under penalty of perjury,
certifying that the company is in compliance with the Commission's ICS
rate rules and adopted payment rules. CenturyLink counters that ``there
is no need for more than a single officer to certify that the company
has complied with Commission rules.''
273. We agree with CenturyLink that ``there is no need for more
than a single officer to certify that the company has complied with
Commission rules.'' We find that, on balance, requiring more than one
officer of an ICS provider to certify to compliance would be
unnecessarily burdensome on some providers and is in fact, contrary to
the manner in which the Commission conducts other annual
certifications. Therefore we adopt CenturyLink's proposal and require
one officer of each ICS provider to annually certify its companies'
compliance with our adopted rules. The annual certification should be
submitted at the same time as the annual report.
L. Consumer Disclosure Requirements
274. Background. In the 2013 Order, the Commission reminded
providers of their current and ongoing obligations to ``comply with
existing Commission rules.'' Specifically, the Commission reminded
providers of their obligations pursuant to section 64.710 of our rules,
which requires providers of inmate operator services to disclose to the
consumer the total cost of the call prior to connecting it, including
any surcharges or premise-imposed fees that may apply to the call as
well as methods by which to make complaints concerning the charges or
collection practices. Additionally, ICS providers that are non-dominant
interexchange carriers must make their current rates, terms, and
conditions available to the public via their company Web sites. Any
violation of such responsibilities, or failure to comply with existing
rules, may subject ICS providers to enforcement action, including,
among other penalties, the imposition of monetary forfeitures.
275. In the Second FNPRM, the Commission sought comment on ``how to
ensure that rates and fees are more transparent to consumers'' and
specifically on the requirement that ICS providers notify their
customers regarding the ICS options available to them and the cost of
those options. ICS providers that offer interstate toll
[[Page 79173]]
service are already required to post their rates on their Web sites,
and, to the extent they offer inmate operator services, their live
agents are already required to make certain notifications to customers.
The Commission sought comment on whether providers' Web sites,
automated IVRs, and live agents should be required to offer in a more
prominent fashion no-cost or lower-cost options before offering other,
higher-priced optional services. The Commission also sought comment on
two reform proposals that offered suggestions for requiring the
publication of ancillary service charges.
276. The Joint Provider Proposal, acknowledging existing
requirements for providers to publish interstate rates, terms and
conditions on their Web sites, offered a detailed proposal regarding
notification requirements for so-called ``convenience or premium
payment options,'' and suggested that all providers be required to
``clearly and conspicuously identify the required information . . . so
that it is actually noticed and understood by the customer.''
Specifically, the Joint Provider Proposal suggests that an ICS provider
``may provide this information to consumers (1) on its Web site, (2) in
its web-posted rates, terms, and conditions, (3) orally when provided
in a slow and deliberate manner and in a reasonably understandable
volume, or (4) in other printed materials provided to a customer.'' The
providers that signed on to the Joint Provider Proposal suggest that
``clear and conspicuous'' means that ``notice would be apparent to the
reasonable customer,'' and that to determine the effectiveness of the
disclosure, the Commission should ``consider the prominence of the
disclosure in comparison to other information, the proximity and
placement of the information, the absence of distracting elements, and
the clarity and understandability of the text of the disclosure.'' Pay
Tel suggests that on a Web site, postings must list call rates and
fees, as well as refund instructions. Pay Tel also suggests that the
vendor Web site must provide a link to the FCC Enforcement Bureau Web
site and the applicable state regulatory agency Web site. Pay Tel also
suggests making facility-specific printed material available at each
facility. The Commission explicitly sought comment on these proposals
in the Second FNPRM.
277. In comments to the Second FNPRM, CenturyLink notes that
especially in jails and short-term facilities, payment decisions are
``typically made in `real-time,' as the call is received from the
inmate'' and that ``there is no reasonable way for called parties to
make informed decisions unless the ICS provider proactively informs
them of options in clear, concise language prior to payment.''
CenturyLink further asserts that ``simple posting[s] on Web sites or
reactive responses upon request are not sufficient'' when faced with
time-sensitive situations such as initial incarceration. The record
indicates that many consumers face the problem of uncertainty with
respect to the cost of ICS. Praeses argues that in addition to
disclosing their ancillary service charges in a prominent location on
their Web sites, providers should be required to disclose all
applicable fees at the time that a consumer seeks a service that is
subject to an ancillary service charge from a provider, but prior to
the inmate or call recipient incurring the fee. DC Prisoners' Project
of the Washington Lawyers' Committee suggests that the Commission
require all ICS providers to train their staff to disclose all rate and
fee information to anyone who contacts the provider. In addition to the
suggestions in the Joint Provider Proposal, GTL asserts that the
Commission ``should enforce its existing requirements regarding oral
disclosures and the posting of rates, terms, and conditions.'' GTL
notes that ``ICS providers have `ongoing responsibilities' to comply
with these existing rules, and violations of those responsibilities or
failure to comply with those existing rules could subject ICS providers
to enforcement action.''
278. Discussion. We believe that transparency in rates, terms, and
fees will facilitate compliance with the reforms and ensure that
consumers are informed of their choices. We find persuasive arguments
that ICS payment decisions are often made in ``real time,'' especially
in short-term detention facilities, and ``there is no reasonable way
for called parties to make informed decisions'' unless rates and terms
are clearly available for consumers prior to the commencement of the
call. For example, transparency about the rates charged for ICS will
provide substantial consumer protection benefits by empowering
consumers to make informed decisions about the ICS offerings they
decide to use. We also applaud voluntary commitments that enhance
transparency for consumers. Here, we supplement our existing rules to
require ICS providers to clearly and accurately disclose their
interstate, international and intrastate rates and ancillary service
charges to consumers. The new rule we adopt will provide key consumer
benefits with minimal burden on ICS providers. Ensuring that end users
know the costs of the services they seek to use will help consumers
make informed decisions about what types of services they can afford
and for what amount of time.
279. We do not mandate a specific format for how consumer
disclosures must be made. Rather, we find that suggestions for
disclosure such as those in the Joint Provider Proposal offer a
reasonable framework as to how to make these disclosures. However, we
note that this would not necessarily be the only framework for
compliance. We will formally evaluate the reasonableness of the Joint
Provider Proposal and any other disclosure formats if and when
complaints arise as to the adequacy of the disclosures. We note that
each failure to disclose all charges to consumers is counted as an
individual violation, which should create a significant incentive for
compliance. In addition, the Commission shall evaluate disclosures of
all consumer charges for reasonableness, in part, on the basis of the
following factors:
Disclosure of information regarding all material charges,
such as the applicable rate, any and all ancillary service charges--
whether one time or recurring--including those to initiate service, and
the name, definition and cost of each rate or fee;
Use of plain language accessible to current and
prospective end users;
Description of single call and related services and
disclosures making clear that consumers have less-costly options rather
than single call and related services;
Ability of end users to easily understand the disclosure;
Timeliness of any updates/changes to the rates and fees,
prior to any updates/changes;
Availability of the disclosure in a prominent location on
the ICS provider's Web site;
Listing of the name, address, and toll-free number of the
ICS provider; and
Listing of the toll-free number for the FCC Consumer Help
Center (888-225-5322).
280. Providers should already be informing customers about the
total amount on a per-call basis that they will be charged so the
disclosure requirements should not be onerous or a significant new
burden. Indeed, the addition to our rules with respect to ancillary
service charges should in fact simplify transparency, as it greatly
reduces the number and variable rates of allowable ancillary service
charges, and thus charges ICS providers must disclose to consumers.
This information
[[Page 79174]]
is relevant to consumer decision making, and the providers must also
keep this information in order to comply with the Annual Reporting and
Certification Requirements adopted herein.
281. The new disclosure rule discussed above falls well within the
confines of the First Amendment. As explained, these disclosures serve
important government purposes, ensuring that end users have accurate
and accessible information about ICS providers' services. This
information is central both to preventing consumer deception and to the
overall deployment and operation of ICS.
282. The Supreme Court has made plain in Zauderer v. Office of
Disciplinary Counsel of Supreme Court of Ohio that the government has
broad discretion in requiring the disclosure of information to prevent
consumer deception and ensure complete information in the marketplace.
Under Zauderer, mandatory factual disclosures will be sustained ``as
long as disclosure requirements are reasonably related to the State's
interest in preventing deception to consumers.'' As the Court observed,
``the First Amendment interests implicated by disclosure requirements
are substantially weaker than those at stake when speech is actually
suppressed.'' The DC Circuit recently reaffirmed these principles in
American Meat Institute v. United States Department of Agriculture, an
en banc decision in which the Court joined the First and Second Circuit
Courts of Appeals in recognizing that other government interests beyond
preventing consumer deception may be invoked to sustain a disclosure
mandate under Zauderer.
283. The new disclosure rule and disclosure language suggested in
this Order clearly pass muster under these precedents. Preventing
consumer deception in the ICS market lies at the heart of the
disclosure rule we adopt today. The Commission has found that ICS
providers have the incentive and ability to engage in harmful
practices, as discussed above. Similarly, the suggested disclosure
language is designed to prevent confusion to all consumers of the ICS
providers' services, and serve to curb providers' incentives to engage
in harmful practices by shedding light on the business practices of ICS
providers. Accurate information about ICS provider offerings encourages
consumer choice and the widespread deployment of ICS. In sum, the
government interests supporting the disclosure rule (as well as the
suggested disclosure language), in addition to the interest of
preventing consumer deception, are substantial and justify our consumer
disclosure suggestions.
284. In addition, the disclosure rule adopted in this Order meets
the analysis the Supreme Court developed for commercial speech cases in
Central Hudson Gas & Elec. Corp. v. Public Serv. Comm'n. Central
Hudson's test first asks whether the expression is protected by the
First Amendment, which requires that the speech concern lawful activity
and not be misleading. Next, the Court asks whether the asserted
governmental interest is substantial. If the first two prongs of the
analysis are met, the Court then determines whether the regulation
directly advances the governmental interest asserted and whether it is
not more extensive than necessary to serve that interest. Requiring ICS
providers to disclose information about ICS rates meets this four-part
test. First, ICS providers' rate information qualifies as an expression
protected by the First Amendment, as it is speech concerning lawful
activity that is not misleading. Second, as explained elsewhere in this
Order, the Commission has a substantial interest in consumer protection
and advancing the public interest, particularly where, as here,
Congress has directed the Commission to ensure that ICS rates are just,
reasonable and fair, pursuant to regulations that redound ``to the
benefit of the general public.'' Third, as explained above, the
regulation directly advances the public interest and consumer
protection in requiring disclosure of this information, as transparency
in rates and charges allows consumers to make more informed choices.
Finally, this new consumer disclosure requirement is not more extensive
than is necessary to protect consumers. Since ICS providers have
already been operating under similar requirements, this information is
readily available to them and, as explained above, we do not prescribe
a particular format for how consumer disclosures must be made, thereby
affording providers leeway to comply with the revised rule in a
flexible, individualized manner that minimizes burden.
285. Cost-Benefit Analysis. We find that, on balance, requiring ICS
providers to disclose information for their intrastate, interstate and
international ICS rates, categorized by facility and size of facility,
as well as ancillary service charges, is not overly burdensome. These
requirements are necessary to ensuring that end users know the costs of
the services they seek to use and helps consumers make informed
decisions about what types of services they can afford and for what
amount of time.
286. The Commission has found that ICS providers have the incentive
and ability to engage in harmful practices, as discussed above.
Commenters have asked the Commission to mandate additional disclosure
and transparency regarding ICS rates and fees. Similarly, these
disclosure requirements are designed to prevent confusion to all
consumers of the ICS providers' services, and serve to curb providers'
incentives by shedding light on the business practices of ICS
providers. Numerous commenters support these reforms.
287. These requirements provide key consumer benefits with minimal
burden on ICS providers. Providers currently are required to post their
rates publicly on their Web sites. Additionally, providers must keep
this information to comply with the Mandatory Data Collection and
Annual Reporting and Certification Requirements adopted herein.
288. To minimize any potential burden on providers, the Commission
does not prescribe a particular format for how consumer disclosures
must be made, but suggests a framework for consideration and allows
providers flexibility in adopting such disclosures, thus allowing
providers with maximum flexibility and minimum burden.
M. Severability
289. All of the rules that are adopted in this Order are designed
to ensure just, reasonable, and fair ICS rates. Each of the reforms we
undertake in this Order serve a particular function toward this goal.
Therefore, it is our intent that each of the rules and regulations
adopted herein shall be severable. We believe that ICS end users will
benefit from the rates caps adopted and will also benefit separately
from the adopted ancillary service charge caps. If any of the rules or
regulations, or portions thereof including, for example, any portion of
our rate caps and ancillary service charge rules, are declared invalid
or unenforceable for any reason, it is our intent that the remaining
rules shall be in full force and effect.
N. Outstanding Petitions
290. After the Commission released the 2013 Order, numerous
entities petitioned the Commission for a stay of the new rules and
requirements. The requests for stay generally expressed concern about
one or more of the following categories of issues: (1) That a ``one-
size-fits-all'' approach for ICS rate reform will be ineffective, and
ignores the fact that jails incur real costs
[[Page 79175]]
and will face budget shortfalls under the Commission's adopted
approach; (2) the continued need for site commissions, or a concern
about how to manage correctional budgets built on a reliance on those
site commissions; (3) a concern about the Commission seeking comment on
asserting jurisdiction over intrastate ICS calls or classifying all ICS
calls as interstate; (4) a potentially harmful impact on the security
at facilities and the safety of citizens stemming from the Commission's
rules and requirements; and (5) general requests that the Commission
stay its Order with no legal analysis or justifications for the
request. We dismiss the first four categories on the basis that the
present order adequately addresses and answers the arguments and
concerns contained within them. We adopt tiered rate caps based on
population size, address site commissions and security concerns, as
well as assert jurisdiction over intrastate ICS, in this Order. We
dismiss the fifth category of stay requests on the basis that they do
not present any legal reasoning or analysis to justify a stay of our
rules and have been rendered moot by this Order.
O. Ex Parte Requirements
291. This proceeding shall be treated as a ``permit-but-disclose''
proceeding in accordance with the Commission's ex parte rules. Persons
making ex parte presentations must file a copy of any written
presentation or a memorandum summarizing any oral presentation within
two business days after the presentation (unless a different deadline
applicable to the Sunshine period applies). Persons making oral ex
parte presentations are reminded that memoranda summarizing the
presentation must (1) list all persons attending or otherwise
participating in the meeting at which the ex parte presentation was
made, and (2) summarize all data presented and arguments made during
the presentation. Memoranda must contain a summary of the substance of
the ex parte presentation ad not merely a list of the subjects
discussed. More than a one or two sentence description of the views and
arguments presented is generally required. If the oral presentation
consisted in whole or in part of the presentation of data or arguments
already reflected in the presenter's written comments, memoranda or
other filings in the proceeding, the presenter may provide citations to
such data or arguments in his or her prior comments, memoranda, or
other filings (specifying the relevant page and/or paragraph numbers
where such data or arguments can be found) in lieu of summarizing them
in the memorandum. Documents shown or given to Commission staff during
ex parte meetings are deemed to be written ex parte presentations and
must be filed consistent with rule 1.1206(b). In proceedings governed
by rule 1.49(f) or for which the Commission has made available a method
of electronic filing, written ex parte presentations and memoranda
summarizing oral ex parte presentations, and all attachments thereto,
must be filed through the electronic comment filing system available
for that proceeding, and must be filed in their native format (e.g.,
.doc, .xml, .ppt, searchable .pdf). Participants in this proceeding
should familiarize themselves with the Commission's ex parte rules.
P. Paperwork Reduction Act Analysis
292. This Report and Order contains new or modified information
collection requirements subject to the Paperwork Reduction Act of 1995
(PRA), Public Law 104-13. It will be submitted to the Office of
Management and Budget (OMB) for review under section 3507(d) of the
PRA. OMB, the general public, and other Federal agencies are invited to
comment on the new or modified information collection requirements
contained in the proceeding. In addition, we note that pursuant to the
Small Business Paperwork Relief Act of 2002, Public Law 107-198, see 44
U.S.C. 3506(4), we previously sought comment on how the Commission
might further reduce the information collection burden for small
business concerns with fewer than 25 employees.
Q. Congressional Review Act
293. The Commission will send a copy of this Report and Order in a
report to be sent to Congress and the Government Accountability Office
pursuant to the Congressional Review Act. See 5 U.S.C. 801(a)(1)(A).
R. Final Regulatory Flexibility Analysis
1. As required by the Regulatory Flexibility Act of 1980, as
amended (RFA). an Initial Regulatory Flexibility Analysis (IRFA) was
incorporated in the Second Notice of Proposed Rulemaking (Second FNPRM)
in WC Docket 12-375. The Commission sought written public comment on
the proposals in the Second FNPRM, including comment on the IRFA. The
Commission did not receive comments directed toward the IRFA. This
Final Regulatory Flexibility Analysis (FRFA) conforms to the RFA.
1. Need for, and Objectives of, the Report and Order
294. The Second Report and Order (Order) adopted rules to ensure
that interstate, intrastate, and international inmate calling service
(ICS) rates in correctional institutions are just, reasonable, and
fair. In the initiating Second FNPRM, the Commission sought information
on issues related to the ICS market, payments to correctional
facilities, ICS interstate and intrastate rates, ancillary fees,
additional ways to promote competition, harmonization of state
regulations, existing contracts, transition periods, accessible ICS,
advanced ICS, periodic review, enforcement, and a cost/benefit analysis
of reform proposals.
295. In this Order, the Commission adopts comprehensive reform of
all aspects of ICS to correct a market failure, foster market
efficiencies, encourage ongoing state reforms and ensure that ICS rates
and charges comply with the Communications Act. The Order does this by
addressing interstate and intrastate ICS rates, payments to
correctional facilities, ancillary service charges, connection and per-
call charges, flat-rate charges, harmonization with state regulations,
disability access, transition periods, periodic review, mandatory data
collection, waivers, and consumer protection measures such as annual
certification and reporting requirements. The reforms adopted in this
Order apply to ICS offered in all correctional facility types and
regardless of technology used to deliver the services.
2. Summary of Significant Issues Raised by Public Comments in Response
to the IRFA
296. The Commission did not receive comments specifically
addressing the rules and policies proposed in the IRFA.
3. Description and Estimate of the Number of Small Entities to Which
Rules Will Apply
297. Small Businesses. Nationwide, there are a total of
approximately 27.9 million small businesses, according to the SBA.
298. Wired Telecommunications Carriers. The SBA has developed a
small business size standard for Wired Telecommunications Carriers,
which consists of all such companies having 1,500 or fewer employees.
According to Census Bureau data for 2007, there were 3,188 firms in
this category, total, that operated for the entire year. Of this total,
3,144 firms had employment of 999 or fewer employees, and 44 firms had
employment of 1,000 employees or
[[Page 79176]]
more. Thus, under this size standard, the majority of firms can be
considered small.
299. Local Exchange Carriers (LECs). Neither the Commission nor the
SBA has developed a size standard for small businesses specifically
applicable to local exchange services. The closest applicable size
standard under SBA rules is for Wired Telecommunications Carriers.
Under that size standard, such a business is small if it has 1,500 or
fewer employees. According to Commission data, 1,307 carriers reported
that they were incumbent local exchange service providers. Of these
1,307 carriers, an estimated 1,006 have 1,500 or fewer employees and
301 have more than 1,500 employees. Consequently, the Commission
estimates that most providers of local exchange service are small
entities that may be affected by the Commission's action.
300. Incumbent Local Exchange Carriers (incumbent LECs). Neither
the Commission nor the SBA has developed a size standard for small
businesses specifically applicable to incumbent local exchange
services. The closest applicable size standard under SBA rules is for
Wired Telecommunications Carriers. Under that size standard, such a
business is small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees. According to
Commission data, 1,307 carriers reported that they were incumbent local
exchange service providers. Of these 1,307 carriers, an estimated 1,006
have 1,500 or fewer employees and 301 have more than 1,500 employees.
Consequently, the Commission estimates that most providers of incumbent
local exchange service are small businesses that may be affected by the
Commission's action.
301. The Commission has included small incumbent LECs in this
present RFA analysis. As noted above, a ``small business'' under the
RFA is one that, inter alia, meets the pertinent small business size
standard (e.g., a telephone communications business having 1,500 or
fewer employees), and ``is not dominant in its field of operation.''
The SBA's Office of Advocacy contends that, for RFA purposes, small
incumbent LECs are not dominant in their field of operation because any
such dominance is not ``national'' in scope. The Commission has
therefore included small incumbent LECs in this RFA analysis, although
it emphasizes that this RFA action has no effect on Commission analyses
and determinations in other, non-RFA contexts.
302. Competitive Local Exchange Carriers (Competitive LECs),
Competitive Access Providers (CAPs), Shared-Tenant Service Providers,
and Other Local Service Providers. Neither the Commission nor the SBA
has developed a small business size standard specifically for these
service providers. The appropriate size standard under SBA rules is for
the category Wired Telecommunications Carriers. Under that size
standard, such a business is small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees.
According to Commission data, 1,442 carriers reported that they were
engaged in the provision of either competitive local exchange services
or competitive access provider services. Of these 1,442 carriers, an
estimated 1,256 have 1,500 or fewer employees and 186 have more than
1,500 employees. In addition, 17 carriers have reported that they are
Shared-Tenant Service Providers, and all 17 are estimated to have 1,500
or fewer employees. In addition, 72 carriers have reported that they
are Other Local Service Providers. Of the 72, 70 have 1,500 or fewer
employees and two have more than 1,500 employees. Consequently, the
Commission estimates that most providers of competitive local exchange
service, competitive access providers, Shared-Tenant Service Providers,
and Other Local Service Providers are small entities that may be
affected by the Commission's action.
303. Interexchange Carriers (IXCs). Neither the Commission nor the
SBA has developed a size standard for small businesses specifically
applicable to interexchange services. The closest applicable size
standard under SBA rules is for Wired Telecommunications Carriers.
Under that size standard, such a business is small if it has 1,500 or
fewer employees. According to Commission data, 359 companies reported
that their primary telecommunications service activity was the
provision of interexchange services. Of these 359 companies, an
estimated 317 have 1,500 or fewer employees and 42 have more than 1,500
employees. Consequently, the Commission estimates that the majority of
interexchange service providers are small entities that may be affected
by the Commission's action.
304. Local Resellers. The SBA has developed a small business size
standard for the category of Telecommunications Resellers. Under that
size standard, such a business is small if it has 1,500 or fewer
employees. According to Commission data, 213 carriers have reported
that they are engaged in the provision of local resale services. Of
these, an estimated 211 have 1,500 or fewer employees and two have more
than 1,500 employees. Consequently, the Commission estimates that the
majority of local resellers are small entities that may be affected by
the Commission's action.
305. Toll Resellers. The SBA has developed a small business size
standard for the category of Telecommunications Resellers. Under that
size standard, such a business is small if it has 1,500 or fewer
employees. According to Commission data, 881 carriers have reported
that they are engaged in the provision of toll resale services. Of
these, an estimated 857 have 1,500 or fewer employees and 24 have more
than 1,500 employees. Consequently, the Commission estimates that the
majority of toll resellers are small entities that may be affected by
the Commission's action.
306. Other Toll Carriers. Neither the Commission nor the SBA has
developed a size standard for small businesses specifically applicable
to Other Toll Carriers. This category includes toll carriers that do
not fall within the categories of interexchange carriers, operator
service providers, prepaid calling card providers, satellite service
carriers, or toll resellers. The closest applicable size standard under
SBA rules is for Wired Telecommunications Carriers. Under that size
standard, such a business is small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees.
According to Commission data, 284 companies reported that their primary
telecommunications service activity was the provision of other toll
carriage. Of these, an estimated 279 have 1,500 or fewer employees and
five have more than 1,500 employees. Consequently, the Commission
estimates that most Other Toll Carriers are small entities that may be
affected by the Commission's action.
307. Payphone Service Providers (PSPs). Neither the Commission nor
the SBA has developed a small business size standard specifically for
payphone services providers. The appropriate size standard under SBA
rules is for the category Wired Telecommunications Carriers. Under that
size standard, such a business is small if it has 1,500 or fewer
employees. According to Commission data, 535 carriers have reported
that they are engaged in the provision of payphone services. Of these,
an estimated 531 have 1,500 or fewer employees and four have more than
1,500 employees. Consequently, the Commission estimates that the
majority of payphone service providers are small entities that may be
affected by the Commission's action.
[[Page 79177]]
4. Description of Projected Reporting, Recordkeeping, and Other
Compliance Requirements for Small Entities
308. Recordkeeping, Reporting, and Certification. The Order
requires that all ICS providers file annually data, categorized by
facility and size of facility, on their current intrastate, interstate,
and international ICS rates. The Commission also requires ICS providers
to file their current ancillary service charge amounts and the
instances of use of each. ICS providers that make site commission
payments must file the monthly amount of any such payment. The
Commission requires ICS providers that provided video visitation
services, either as a form of ICS or not, during the reporting period,
to file the minutes of use and per-minute rates for those services. As
discussed in greater detail in the Disability Access section above, the
Commission also requires that ICS providers report: (1) The number of
disability-related calls they provided; (2) the number of problems they
experienced with such calls; and (3) the number of complaints they
received related to access to ICS by TTY and TRS users e.g., dropped
calls, poor call quality and the number of incidences of each. The
adopted reporting requirements will facilitate enforcement and act as
an additional means of ensuring that ICS providers' rates and practices
are just, reasonable, fair and in compliance with the Order.
309. The Commission delegates to the Wireline Competition Bureau
(Bureau) the authority to adopt a template for submitting the required
data, information, and certifications.
5. Steps Taken To Minimize the Significant Economic Impact on Small
Entities, and Significant Alternatives Considered
310. The RFA requires an agency to describe any significant,
specifically small business, alternatives that it has considered in
reaching its proposed approach, which may include the following four
alternatives (among others): ``(1) the establishment of differing
compliance or reporting requirements or timetables that take into
account the resources available to small entities; (2) the
clarification, consolidation, or simplification of compliance and
reporting requirements under the rules for such small entities; (3) the
use of performance rather than design standards; and (4) an exemption
from coverage of the rule, or any part thereof, for such small
entities.''
311. The Commission needs access to data that are comprehensive,
reliable, sufficiently disaggregated, and reported in a standardized
manner. The Order recognizes, however, that reporting obligations
impose burdens on the reporting providers. Consequently, the Commission
limits its collection to information that is narrowly tailored to meet
its needs.
312. Monitoring and Certification. The Commission requires ICS
providers to submit annually their data on their intrastate, interstate
and international ICS rates, categorized by facility and size of
facility. The Commission requires ICS providers to file their charges
to consumers that are ancillary to providing the telecommunications
piece of ICS. Providers are currently required to post their rates
publicly on their Web sites. Thus, this additional filing requirement
should entail minimal additional compliance burden, even for the
largest ICS providers.
313. The information on providers' Web sites is not certified and
is generally not available in a format that will provide the per-call
details that the Commission requires to meet its statutory obligations.
Thus, the Commission further requires each provider to annually certify
its compliance with other portions of the Order. The Commission finds
that without a uniform, comprehensive dataset with which to evaluate
ICS providers' rates, the Commission's analyses will be incomplete. The
Commission recognizes that any information collection imposes burdens,
which may be most keenly felt by smaller providers, but concludes that
the benefits of having comprehensive data substantially outweigh the
burdens. Additionally, some of these potential burdens, such as the
filing of rates currently required to be posted on an ICS provider's
Web site, are minimally burdensome.
314. Data Collection. The Commission is cognizant of the burdens of
data collections, and has therefore taken steps to minimize burdens,
including directing the Bureau to adopt a template for filing the data
that minimizes burdens on providers by maximizing uniformity and ease
of filing, while still allowing the Commission to gather the necessary
data. The Commission also finds that without a uniform, comprehensive
dataset with which to evaluate ICS providers' costs, its analyses will
be incomplete, and its ability to establish ICS rate caps will be
severely impaired. The Commission thus concludes that requiring ICS
providers to report this cost data appropriately balances any burdens
of reporting with the Commission's need for the data required to carry
out its statutory duties.
6. Report to Congress
315. The Commission will send a copy of the Order, including this
FRFA, in a report to be sent to Congress pursuant to the Small Business
Regulatory Enforcement Fairness Act of 1996. In addition, the
Commission will send a copy of the Order, including this FRFA, to the
Chief Counsel for Advocacy of the Small Business Administration. A copy
of the Order and FRFA (or summaries thereof) will also be published in
the Federal Register.
V. Ordering Clauses
316. Accordingly, it is ordered that, pursuant to sections 1, 2,
4(i)-(j), 201(b), 215, 218, 220, 276, 303(r), and 403 of the
Communications Act of 1934, as amended, 47 U.S.C. 151, 152, 154(i)-(j),
201(b), 215, 218, 220, 276, 303(r), and 403 this Second Report and
Order is adopted.
317. It is further ordered that Part 64 of the Commission's Rules,
47 CFR part 64, is amended as set forth in Appendix A of the Second
Report and Order. These rules shall become effective March 17, 2016.
318. It is further ordered, that the prohibition against entering
into new contracts,--or negotiating amendments to existing contracts,
as discussed in paragraphs 261 and 262, herein, shall take effect
immediately upon publication in the Federal Register.
319. It is further ordered, that the Commission's Consumer and
Governmental Affairs Bureau, Reference Information Center, shall send a
copy of this Second Report and Order, including the Final Regulatory
Flexibility Analysis, to the Chief Counsel for Advocacy of the Small
Business Administration.
320. It is further ordered, that pursuant to sections 1.4(b)(1) and
1.103(a) of the Commission's rules, 47 CFR 1.4(b)(1) and 1.103(a), that
the Compliance date for this Second Report and Order shall be January
19, 2016.
List of Subjects in 47 CFR Part 64
Claims, Communications common carriers, Computer technology,
Credit, Foreign relations, Individuals with disabilities, Political
candidates, Radio, Reporting and recordkeeping requirements,
Telecommunications, Telegraph, Telephone.
[[Page 79178]]
Federal Communications Commission.
Gloria J. Miles,
Federal Register Liaison Officer, Office of the Secretary.
Final Rules
For the reasons discussed in the preamble, the Federal
Communications Commission amends 47 CFR part 64 as follows:
PART 64--MISCELLANEOUS RULES RELATING TO COMMON CARRIERS
0
1. The authority citation for part 64 continues to read as follows:
Authority: 47 U.S.C. 154, 254(k); 403(b)(2)(B), (c), Pub. L.
104-104, 110 Stat. 56. Interpret or apply 47 U.S.C. 201, 218, 222,
225, 226, 227, 228, 254(k), 616, 620, and the Middle Class Tax
Relief and Job Creation Act of 2012, Pub. L. 112-96, unless
otherwise noted.
0
2. Section 64.6000 is revised to read as follows:
Sec. 64.6000 Definitions.
As used in this subpart:
(a) Ancillary Service Charge means any charge Consumers may be
assess for the use of Inmate Calling services that are not included in
the per-minute charges assessed for individual calls. Ancillary Service
Charges that may be charged include the following. All other Ancillary
Service Charges are prohibited.
(1) Automated Payment Fees means credit card payment, debit card
payment, and bill processing fees, including fees for payments made by
interactive voice response (IVR), web, or kiosk;
(2) Fees for Single-Call and Related Services means billing
arrangements whereby an Inmate's collect calls are billed through a
third party on a per-call basis, where the called party does not have
an account with the Provider of Inmate Calling Services or does not
want to establish an account;
(3) Live Agent Fee means a fee associated with the optional use of
a live operator to complete Inmate Calling Services transactions;
(4) Paper Bill/Statement Fees means fees associated with providing
customers of Inmate Calling Services an optional paper billing
statement;
(5) Third-Party Financial Transaction Fees means the exact fees,
with no markup, that Providers of Inmate Calling Services are charged
by third parties to transfer money or process financial transactions to
facilitate a Consumer's ability to make account payments via a third
party.
(b) Authorized Fee means a government authorized, but
discretionary, fee which a Provider must remit to a federal, state, or
local government, and which a Provider is permitted, but not required,
to pass through to Consumers. An Authorized Fee may not include a
markup, unless the markup is specifically authorized by a federal,
state, or local statute, rule, or regulation.
(c) Average Daily Population (ADP) means the sum of all inmates in
a facility for each day of the preceding calendar year, divided by the
number of days in the year. ADP shall be calculated in accordance with
Sec. 64.6010(e) and (f);
(d) Collect Calling means an arrangement whereby the called party
takes affirmative action clearly indicating that it will pay the
charges associated with a call originating from an Inmate Telephone;
(e) Consumer means the party paying a Provider of Inmate Calling
Services;
(f) Correctional Facility or Correctional Institution means a Jail
or a Prison;
(g) Debit Calling means a presubscription or comparable service
which allows an Inmate, or someone acting on an Inmate's behalf, to
fund an account set up though a Provider that can be used to pay for
Inmate Calling Services calls originated by the Inmate;
(h) Flat Rate Calling means a calling plan under which a Provider
charges a single fee for an Inmate Calling Services call, regardless of
the duration of the call;
(i) Inmate means a person detained at a Jail or Prison, regardless
of the duration of the detention;
(j) Inmate Calling Service means a service that allows Inmates to
make calls to individuals outside the Correctional Facility where the
Inmate is being held, regardless of the technology used to deliver the
service;
(k) Inmate Telephone means a telephone instrument, or other device
capable of initiating calls, set aside by authorities of a Correctional
Facility for use by Inmates;
(l) International Calls means calls that originate in the United
States and terminate outside the United States;
(m) Jail means a facility of a local, state, or federal law
enforcement agency that is used primarily to hold individuals who are;
(1) Awaiting adjudication of criminal charges;
(2) Post-conviction and committed to confinement for sentences of
one year or less; or
(3) Post-conviction and awaiting transfer to another facility. The
term also includes city, county or regional facilities that have
contracted with a private company to manage day-to-day operations;
privately-owned and operated facilities primarily engaged in housing
city, county or regional inmates; and facilities used to detain
individuals pursuant to a contract with U.S. Immigration and Customs
Enforcement;
(n) Mandatory Tax or Mandatory Fee means a fee that a Provider is
required to collect directly from Consumers, and remit to federal,
state, or local governments;
(o) Per-Call, or Per-Connection Charge means a one-time fee charged
to a Consumer at call initiation;
(p) Prepaid Calling means a presubscription or comparable service
in which a Consumer, other than an Inmate, funds an account set up
through a Provider of Inmate Calling Services. Funds from the account
can then be used to pay for Inmate Calling Services, including calls
that originate with an Inmate;
(q) Prepaid Collect Calling means a calling arrangement that allows
an Inmate to initiate an Inmate Calling Services call without having a
pre-established billing arrangement and also provides a means, within
that call, for the called party to establish an arrangement to be
billed directly by the Provider of Inmate Calling Services for future
calls from the same Inmate;
(r) Prison means a facility operated by a territorial, state, or
federal agency that is used primarily to confine individuals convicted
of felonies and sentenced to terms in excess of one year. The term also
includes public and private facilities that provide outsource housing
to other agencies such as the State Departments of Correction and the
Federal Bureau of Prisons; and facilities that would otherwise fall
under the definition of a Jail but in which the majority of inmates are
post-conviction or are committed to confinement for sentences of longer
than one year;
(s) Provider of Inmate Calling Services, or Provider means any
communications service provider that provides Inmate Calling Services,
regardless of the technology used;
(t) Site Commission means any form of monetary payment, in-kind
payment, gift, exchange of services or goods, fee, technology
allowance, or product that a Provider of Inmate Calling Services or
affiliate of an Provider of Inmate Calling Services may pay, give,
donate, or otherwise provide to an entity that operates a correctional
institution, an entity with which the Provider of Inmate Calling
Services enters into an agreement to provide ICS, a governmental agency
that oversees a correctional facility, the city, county, or
[[Page 79179]]
state where a facility is located, or an agent of any such facility.
0
3. Section 64.6010 is revised to read as follows:
Sec. 64.6010 Inmate Calling Services rate caps.
(a) No Provider shall charge, in the Jails it serves, a per-minute
rate for Debit Calling, Prepaid Calling, or Prepaid Collect Calling in
excess of:
(1) $0.22 in Jails with an ADP of 0-349;
(2) $0.16 in Jails with an ADP of 350-999; or
(3) $0.14 in Jails with an ADP of 1,000 or greater.
(b) No Provider shall charge, in any Prison it serves, a per-minute
rate for Debit Calling, Prepaid Calling, or Prepaid Collect Calling in
excess of:
(1) $0.11;
(2) [Reserved]
(c) No Provider shall charge, in the Jails it serves, a per-minute
rate for Collect Calling in excess of:
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Collect rate Collect rate Collect rate
Debit/prepaid cap per MOU as cap per MOU as cap per MOU as
Size and type of facility rate cap per of June 20, of July 1, of July 1,
MOU 2016 2017 2018
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
0-349 Jail ADP.................................. $0.22 $0.49 $0.36 $0.22
350-999 Jail ADP................................ 0.16 0.49 0.33 0.16
1,000+ Jail ADP................................. 0.14 0.49 0.32 0.14
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
(d) No Provider shall charge, in the Prisons it serves, a per-
minute rate for Collect Calling in excess of:
(1) $0.14 after March 17, 2016;
(2) $0.13 after July 1, 2017; and
(3) $0.11 after July 1, 2018, and going forward.
(e) For purposes of this section, the initial ADP shall be
calculated, for all of the Correctional Facilities covered by an Inmate
Calling Services contract, by summing the total number of inmates from
January 1, 2015, through January 19, 2016, divided by the number of
days in that time period;
(f) In subsequent years, for all of the correctional facilities
covered by an Inmate Calling Services contract, the ADP will be the sum
of the total number of inmates from January 1st through December 31st
divided by the number of days in the year and will become effective on
January 31st of the following year.
0
4. Section 64.6020 is revised to read as follows:
Sec. 64.6020 Ancillary Service Charge.
(a) No Provider shall charge an Ancillary Service Charge other than
those permitted charges listed in Sec. 64.6000.
(b) No Provider shall charge a rate for a permitted Ancillary
Service Charge in excess of:
(1) For Automated Payment Fees--$3.00 per use;
(2) For Single-Call and Related Services--the exact transaction fee
charged by the third-party provider, with no markup, plus the adopted,
per-minute rate;
(3) For Live Agent Fee--$5.95 per use;
(4) For Paper Bill/Statement Fee--$2.00 per use;
(5) For Third-Party Financial Transaction Fees--the exact fees,
with no markup that result from the transaction.
0
5. Section 64.6030 is revised to read as follows:
Sec. 64.6030 Inmate Calling Services interim rate cap.
No Provider shall charge a rate for Collect Calling in excess of
$0.25 per minute, or a rate for Debit Calling, Prepaid Calling, or
Prepaid Collect Calling in excess of $0.21 per minute. These interim
rate caps shall sunset upon the effectiveness of the rates established
in Sec. 64.6010.
0
6. Section 64.6040 is revised to read as follows:
Sec. 64.6040 Rates for calls involving a TTY device.
(a) No Provider shall levy or collect any charge in excess of 25
percent of the applicable per-minute rate for TTY-to-TTY calls when
such calls are associated with Inmate Calling Services.
(b) No Provider shall levy or collect any charge or fee for TRS-to-
voice or voice-to-TTY calls.
0
7. Section 64.6060 is revised to read as follows:
Sec. 64.6060 Annual reporting and certification requirement.
(a) Providers must submit a report to the Commission, by April 1st
of each year, regarding interstate, intrastate, and international
Inmate Calling Services for the prior calendar year. The report shall
be categorized both by facility type and size and shall contain:
(1) Current interstate, intrastate, and international rates for
Inmate Calling Services;
(2) Current Ancillary Service Charge amounts and the instances of
use of each;
(3) The Monthly amount of each Site Commission paid;
(4) Minutes of use, per-minute rates and ancillary service charges
for video visitation services;
(5) The number of TTY-based Inmate Calling Services calls provided
per facility during the reporting period;
(6) The number of dropped calls the reporting Provider experienced
with TTY-based calls; and
(7) The number of complaints that the reporting Provider received
related to e.g., dropped calls, poor call quality and the number of
incidences of each by TTY and TRS users.
(b) An officer or director of the reporting Provider must certify
that the reported information and data are accurate and complete to the
best of his or her knowledge, information, and belief.
0
8. Section 64.6070 is added to subpart FF to read as follows:
Sec. 64.6070 Taxes and fees.
(a) No Provider shall charge any taxes or fees to users of Inmate
Calling Services, other than those permitted under Sec. 64.6020,
Mandatory Taxes, Mandatory Fees, or Authorized Fees.
0
9. Section 64.6080 is added to subpart FF to read as follows:
Sec. 64.6080 Per-Call, or Per-Connection Charges.
No Provider shall impose a Per-Call or Per-Connection Charge on a
Consumer.
0
10. Section 64.6090 is added to subpart FF to read as follows:
Sec. 64.6090 Flat-Rate Calling.
No Provider shall offer Flat-Rate Calling for Inmate Calling
Services.
0
11. Section 64.6100 is added to subpart FF to read as follows:
Sec. 64.6100 Minimum and maximum Prepaid Calling account balances.
(a) No Provider shall institute a minimum balance requirement for a
Consumer to use Debit or Prepaid Calling.
(b) No Provider shall prohibit a consumer from depositing at least
$50
[[Page 79180]]
per transaction to fund a Debit or Prepaid Calling account.
0
12. Section 64.6110 is added to subpart FF to read as follows:
Sec. 64.6110 Consumer disclosure of Inmate Calling Services rates.
Providers must clearly, accurately, and conspicuously disclose
their interstate, intrastate, and international rates and Ancillary
Service Charges to consumers on their Web sites or in another
reasonable manner readily available to consumers.
[FR Doc. 2015-31252 Filed 12-17-15; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6712-01-P