Updating Competitive Bidding Rules; Expanding the Economic and Innovation Opportunities of Spectrum Through Incentive Auctions; Implementation of the Commercial Spectrum Enhancement Act, 68172-68202 [2014-26924]
Download as PDF
68172
Federal Register / Vol. 79, No. 220 / Friday, November 14, 2014 / Proposed Rules
(iii) Table. The following Table 2
identifies the crop subgroups for Crop
Group 24, specifies the representative
commodities for each subgroup, and
lists all the commodities included in
each subgroup.
TABLE 2—CROP GROUP 24: SUBGROUP LISTING
Representative
commodities
Commodities
Crop Subgroup 24A. Small fruit, inedible peel subgroup
Lychee ......................
´
Aisen; bael fruit; Burmese grape; cat’s eyes; inga; lychee; madras-thorn; manduro; matisia; mesquite; mongongo, fruit;
pawpaw, small-flower; satinleaf; Sierra Leone-tamarind; Spanish lime; velvet tamarind; wampi; white star apple;
cultivars, varieties, and hybrids of these commodities.
Crop Subgroup 24B. Medium to large fruit, smooth, inedible peel subgroup
Avocado, plus pomegranate or banana.
Abiu; akee apple; avocado; avocado, Guatemalan; avocado, Mexican; avocado, West Indian; bacury; banana; banana,
´
´
dwarf; binjai; canistel; cupuacu; etambe; jatoba; kei apple; langstat; lanjut; lucuma; mabolo; mango; mango, horse;
mango, Saipan; mangosteen; paho; papaya; pawpaw, common; pelipisan; pequi; pequia; persimmon, American; plantain; pomegranate; poshte; quandong; sapote, black; sapote, green; sapote, white; sataw; screw-pine; star apple; tamarind-of-the-Indies; wild loquat; cultivars, varieties, and hybrids of these commodities.
Crop Subgroup 24C. Medium to large fruit, rough or hairy, inedible peel subgroup
Pineapple, plus
Atemoya or sugar
apple.
Atemoya; biriba; breadfruit; champedak; cherimoya; custard apple; durian; elephant-apple; ilama; jackfruit; karuka;
longan; mammy-apple; marmalade-box; marang; monkey-bread tree; nicobar-breadfruit; pandanus; pineapple; pulasan;
rambutan; sapodilla; sapote, mamey; soncoya; soursop; sugar apple; sun sapote; cultivars, varieties, and hybrids of
these commodities.
Crop Subgroup 24D. Cactus, inedible peel subgroup
Dragon fruit and
Prickly pear fruit.
Dragon fruit; pitahaya; pitaya; pitaya amarilla; pitaya roja; pitaya, yellow; prickly pear, fruit; prickly pear, Texas, fruit;
saguaro; cultivars, varieties, and hybrids of these commodities.
Crop Subgroup 24E. Vine, inedible peel subgroup
Passionfruit ...............
Granadilla; granadilla, giant; monstera; passionflower, winged-stem; passionfruit; passionfruit, banana; passionfruit, purple; passionfruit, yellow; cultivars, varieties, and hybrids of these commodities.
BILLING CODE 6560–50–P
FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS
COMMISSION
47 CFR Parts 1 and 27
[RM–11395, GN Docket No. 12–268, WT
Docket Nos. 14–170, 05–211; FCC 14–146]
Updating Competitive Bidding Rules;
Expanding the Economic and
Innovation Opportunities of Spectrum
Through Incentive Auctions;
Implementation of the Commercial
Spectrum Enhancement Act
Federal Communications
Commission.
ACTION: Proposed rule.
AGENCY:
This Notice of Proposed
Rulemaking (NPRM) seeks comment on
the revision of certain competitive
bidding rules and provides notice of the
Commission’s intention to resolve
longstanding petitions for
reconsideration.
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with PROPOSALS
SUMMARY:
Comments are due on or before
December 29, 2014 and reply comments
are due on or before January 20, 2015.
DATES:
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:06 Nov 13, 2014
Jkt 235001
All filings in response to the
NPRM must refer to GN Docket No. 12–
268 and WT Docket Nos. 14–170 and
05–211. The Commission strongly
encourages parties to develop responses
to the NPRM that adhere to the
organization and structure of the NPRM.
Comments may be filed using the
Commission’s Electronic Comment
Filing System (ECFS):
D Electronic Filers: Comments may be
filed electronically using the Internet by
accessing ECFS: https://fjallfoss.fcc.gov/
ecfs2.
D Paper Filers: Parties who choose to
file by paper must file an original and
one copy of each filing. If more than one
docket or rulemaking number appears in
the caption of this proceeding, filers
must submit two additional copies for
each additional docket or rulemaking
number.
Filings can be sent by hand or
messenger delivery, by commercial
overnight courier, or by first-class or
overnight U.S. Postal Service mail. All
filings must be addressed to the
Commission’s Secretary, Office of the
Secretary, Federal Communications
Commission.
All hand-delivered or messengerdelivered paper filings for the
ADDRESSES:
[FR Doc. 2014–26661 Filed 11–13–14; 8:45 am]
PO 00000
Frm 00036
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
Commission’s Secretary must be
delivered to FCC Headquarters at 445
12th Street SW., Room TW–A325,
Washington, DC 20554. The filing hours
are 8:00 a.m. to 7:00 p.m. All hand
deliveries must be held together with
rubber bands or fasteners. Any
envelopes and boxes must be disposed
of before entering the building.
Commercial overnight mail (other
than U.S. Postal Service Express Mail
and Priority Mail) must be sent to 9300
East Hampton Drive, Capitol Heights,
MD 20743.
U.S. Postal Service first-class,
Express, and Priority mail must be
addressed to 445 12th Street SW.,
Washington, DC 20554.
People with Disabilities: To request
materials in accessible formats for
people with disabilities (braille, large
print, electronic files, or audio format),
send an email to fcc504@fcc.gov or call
the Consumer & Governmental Affairs
Bureau at 202–418–0530 (voice), 202–
418–0432 (TTY).
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
Wireless Telecommunications Bureau,
Auctions and Spectrum Access
Division: Kathryn Hinton at (202) 418–
0660.
E:\FR\FM\14NOP1.SGM
14NOP1
Federal Register / Vol. 79, No. 220 / Friday, November 14, 2014 / Proposed Rules
This is a
summary of the Competitive Bidding
NPRM released on October 10, 2014.
The complete text of the Competitive
Bidding NPRM is available for public
inspection and copying from 8:00 a.m.
to 4:30 p.m. Eastern Time (ET) Monday
through Thursday or from 8:00 a.m. to
11:30 a.m. ET on Fridays in the FCC
Reference Information Center, 445 12th
Street SW., Room CY–A257,
Washington, DC 20554. The Competitive
Bidding NPRM may be purchased from
the Commission’s duplicating
contractor, Best Copy and Printing, Inc.
(BCPI), 445 12th Street SW., Room CY–
B402, Washington, DC 20554, telephone
202–488–5300, facsimile 202–488–5563,
or by contacting BCPI on its Web site:
https://www.BCPIWEB.com. When
ordering documents from BCPI, please
provide the appropriate FCC document
number, for example, FCC 14–146. The
complete text is also available on the
Commission’s Web site at https://
wireless.fcc.gov, or by using the search
function on the ECFS Web page at
https://www.fcc.gov/cgb/ecfs.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION:
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with PROPOSALS
Initial Paperwork Reduction Act of
1995 Analysis
The NPRM contains proposed new or
modified information collection
requirements. The Commission, as part
of its continuing effort to reduce
paperwork burdens, invites the general
public and the Office of Management
and Budget (OMB) to comment on the
information collection requirements
contained in this document, as required
by the Paperwork Reduction Act of
1995, Public Law 104–13. In addition,
pursuant to the Small Business
Paperwork Relief Act of 2002, Public
Law 107–198, see 44 U.S.C. 3506(c)(4),
the Commission seeks specific comment
on how it might further reduce the
information collection burden for small
business concerns with fewer than 25
employees.
I. Introduction
1. The Commission proposes to
reform some of its general part 1 rules
governing competitive bidding for
spectrum licenses to reflect changes in
the marketplace, including the
challenges faced by new entrants. The
Commission’s proposals also advance
the statutory directive to ensure that
small businesses, rural telephone
companies, and businesses owned by
members of minority groups and women
(collectively, designated entities or DEs)
are given the opportunity to participate
in the provision of spectrum-based
services, and fulfill the commitment the
Commission made in the Broadcast
Television Spectrum Incentive Auction
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:06 Nov 13, 2014
Jkt 235001
Report & Order. Expanding the
Economic and Innovation Opportunities
of Spectrum Through Incentive
Auctions, 79 FR 48442, Aug. 15, 2014.
Together these proposals will assure
that the Commission’s part 1 rules
continue to promote the Commission’s
fundamental statutory objectives. The
Commission expects to act on the issues
it raises here soon enough to allow all
parties to account for any changes while
planning for the Broadcast Television
Spectrum Incentive Auction
(hereinafter, Incentive Auction or BIA).
2. In the Competitive Bidding NPRM,
the Commission proposes to: (1) Provide
small businesses greater opportunity to
participate in the provision of a wide
range of spectrum-based services by
modifying the Commission’s eligibility
requirements, updating the standardized
schedule of small business sizes, and
eliminating duplicative reporting
requirements, while also seeking
comment on whether to strengthen its
rules to prevent the unjust enrichment
of ineligible entities; (2) Amend the
Commission’s former defaulter rule to
balance concerns that the current rule is
overly broad with the Commission’s
continued need to ensure that auction
bidders are financially reliable; (3)
Codify an established competitive
bidding procedure that prohibits the
same individual or entity from
becoming qualified to bid on the basis
of more than one short-form (FCC Form
175) application in a specific auction;
(4) Prevent entities that are exclusively
controlled by a single individual or set
of individuals from becoming qualified
to bid on overlapping licenses based on
more than one short-form application in
a specific auction; and (5) Retain the
current rules governing joint bidding
arrangements among non-nationwide
providers and prohibit joint bidding
arrangements among nationwide
providers.
3. The Commission also provides
notice of its intention to resolve long
standing petitions for reconsideration
and proposes necessary clean-up
revisions to its part 1 competitive
bidding rules.
II. Eligibility for Bidding Credits
4. In establishing the Commission’s
auction authority, Congress vested the
Commission with broad discretion in
balancing a number of competing
objectives. These included, among other
things, special provisions to ensure that
DEs, including small businesses, have
the opportunity to participate at auction
and in the provision of spectrum-based
services. Section 309(j)(4)(D) of the
Communications Act (the Act) requires
that when the Commission prescribes
PO 00000
Frm 00037
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
68173
regulations in designing systems of
competitive bidding, it shall ‘‘ensure
that small businesses, rural telephone
companies, and businesses owned by
members of minority groups and women
are given the opportunity to participate
in the provision of spectrum-based
services, and, for such purposes,
consider the use of . . . bidding
preferences.’’ In addition, the statute
directs that in designing such systems of
competitive bidding, the Commission
shall seek to promote ‘‘economic
opportunity and competition . . . by
avoiding excessive concentration of
licenses and by disseminating licenses
among a wide variety of applicants,
including small businesses, rural
telephone companies, and businesses
owned by members of minority groups
and women.’’ At the same time, the Act
requires the Commission to ‘‘prevent
unjust enrichment as a result of the
methods employed to issue
licenses. . . .’’
5. The Commission’s challenge in
providing opportunities to small
businesses and entrepreneurs pursuant
to these provisions has always been to
find a reasonable balance between the
competing goals of affording such
entities reasonable flexibility to obtain
the capital necessary to participate in
the provision of spectrum-based
services and effectively preventing the
unjust enrichment of ineligible entities.
See Implementation of the Commercial
Spectrum Enhancement Act and
Modernization of the Commission’s
Competitive Bidding Rules and
Procedures, 71 FR 26245, May 4, 2006
(DE Second Report and Order). Over the
two-decade span of the auctions
program, the Commission has
periodically modified its rules to
achieve the right balance given changing
circumstances in the wireless industry.
6. The Commission takes the
opportunity to consider whether its
rules continue to serve their intended
purposes and the public interest in an
evolving mobile wireless marketplace.
In the past decade, the rapid adoption
of smartphones and tablet computers
and the widespread use of mobile
applications, combined with the
increasing deployment of high-speed 3G
and now 4G technologies, have driven
significantly more intensive use of
mobile networks. This progression from
the provision of mobile voice services to
the provision of mobile broadband
services has increased the need for
access to spectrum. In addition, in the
past decade, the number of small and
regional mobile wireless service
providers has significantly decreased,
yet regional and local service providers
continue to offer consumers additional
E:\FR\FM\14NOP1.SGM
14NOP1
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with PROPOSALS
68174
Federal Register / Vol. 79, No. 220 / Friday, November 14, 2014 / Proposed Rules
choices in the areas they serve. As the
costs of spectrum and network
deployment have increased in the last
20 years, especially for small and new
entrants, access to capital for acquiring
licenses is critical for these providers to
take advantage of different opportunities
to participate in the provision of
spectrum-based services, including
through facilities-based deployment,
spectrum leasing, and mobile virtual
network operator arrangements.
7. The Commission addresses the
concerns of parties that argue that its
current rules inhibit, rather than foster,
the inclusion of small businesses in the
wireless marketplace. The Commission
offers proposals to increase the
opportunities for small businesses to
become spectrum licensees. At the same
time, the Commission remains mindful
of its responsibility to ensure that
benefits are provided only to qualifying
entities and seeks comment on
modifying its current unjust enrichment
rules.
8. As a first step in reassessing how
the Commission determines small
business eligibility, the Commission
proposes to repeal the attributable
material relationship (AMR) rule and to
re-examine the need for the related
decade-old policy that has limited small
businesses seeking bidding credits to
providing primarily retail, facilitiesbased service directly to the public with
each of their licenses. The Commission
proposes to instead adopt a more
flexible approach under which it would
evaluate small business eligibility on a
license-by-license basis, using a twopronged test. Under this proposal, the
Commission would apply existing rules
requiring attribution of controlling
interests in, and affiliates of, a small
business venture to determine whether
the applicant: (1) Meets the applicable
small business size standard, and (2)
retains control over the spectrum
associated with the individual licenses
for which it seeks benefits. The
Commission further proposes to modify
the language of 47 CFR 1.9020 to make
clear that DE lessors may fully engage in
spectrum manager leasing under the
same de facto control standard as nonDE lessors. With these proposals, the
Commission revisits its statutory
mandate under 47 U.S.C. 309(j)(4)(D)
‘‘to ensure that small businesses, rural
telephone companies, and businesses
owned by members of minority groups
and women are given the opportunity to
participate in the provision of spectrumbased services’’ in light of today’s
wireless marketplace. Alternatively, the
Commission also seeks comment on
retaining the policy and/or some
variation of the AMR rule. The
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:06 Nov 13, 2014
Jkt 235001
Commission also asks whether it should
revisit its unjust enrichment rules to
assure that the Commission maintains
the right balance considering its
responsibility to safeguard the award of
small business benefits to only eligible
entities.
9. The Commission also proposes to
modify the generally applicable
schedule of small business size
standards and bidding credits, which
has remained unchanged in the 17 years
since it was first adopted. The goal of
these proposals is to encourage small
business participation in spectrum
license auctions and to ensure that the
Commission’s gross revenue definitions
accurately reflect what constitutes a
‘‘small business’’ in today’s
marketplace, taking into consideration
the relative size of the large, national
providers. Specifically, the Commission
proposes revisions to its small business
definitions and seeks comment on
whether to change the bidding credit
percentages that would apply to those
definitions. The Commission also seeks
comment on whether to offer alternative
bidding preferences to entities based on
criteria other than business size by
revenue.
10. Additionally, the Commission
proposes to repeal the DE annual
reporting requirement. The Commission
questions whether the value of the
information provided in those reports
outweighs the regulatory burden that
the reporting obligation places on small
businesses.
11. Collectively, these proposals seek
to update the Commission’s rules to
reflect that small businesses need
greater opportunities to gain access to
capital so that they may have an
opportunity to participate in the
provision of spectrum-based services in
today’s communications marketplace.
The Commission recognizes that high
capital costs associated with building
and operating wireless broadband
networks may require small businesses
to find alternative revenue streams,
including through secondary markets,
so that they have an opportunity to
acquire licenses at auction and
participate in the provision of spectrumbased services. The Commission
anticipates that by revising its rules to
allow small businesses to take
advantage of the same opportunities to
utilize their spectrum capacity and gain
access to capital as those afforded to
larger licensees, the Commission can
better achieve its statutory directives.
The Commission nonetheless remains
mindful of its obligation to prevent
unjust enrichment of ineligible entities.
The Commission describes and seeks
PO 00000
Frm 00038
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
comment on each of its specific
proposals.
A. Attribution Rules and Small Business
Policies
12. Background. As its principal
means of fulfilling the statutory goals for
DEs, the Commission makes auction
bidding credits available to eligible
small businesses. A small business is
eligible for bidding credits if its gross
revenues, in combination with those of
its ‘‘attributable’’ interest holders, fall
below applicable service-specific
financial caps. Since 2000, the
Commission has applied a ‘‘controlling
interest’’ standard to all services when
making these attribution determinations
in the small business context. Under
this standard, the Commission attributes
to an applicant the gross revenues of the
applicant, its controlling interests, its
affiliates, and the affiliates of the
applicant’s controlling interests. A
‘‘controlling interest’’ includes
individuals or entities, or groups of
individuals or entities, that have control
of the applicant under the principles of
either de jure or de facto control.
Affiliates include entities or individuals
that directly or indirectly control or
have the power to control the applicant,
directly or indirectly are controlled by
the applicant, directly or indirectly are
controlled by a third party that also
controls the applicant, or have an
‘‘identity of interest’’ with the applicant.
13. In adopting secondary markets
rules in the 2004 Secondary Markets
Second Report and Order, the
Commission sought to expand and
enhance secondary markets to permit
spectrum to flow more freely among
users and uses in response to economic
demand, to the extent consistent with
its public interest objectives. Promoting
Efficient Use of Spectrum Through
Elimination of Barriers to the
Development of Secondary Markets,
Second Report and Order, Order on
Reconsideration, and Second Further
Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 69 FR
77522, Dec. 27, 2004 (Secondary
Markets Second Report and Order). The
Commission explained that it intended
for its rules to allow more flexible use
of spectrum by licensees and other
spectrum users, better define licensees’
and spectrum users’ rights and
responsibilities, enable the use of
spectrum across various dimensions
(frequency, space, and time), promote
the efficient use of spectrum, and
provide for continued technological
advances. While the Commission
ostensibly extended the new de facto
control standard for spectrum manager
leasing to DE lessors, it nonetheless
required that a licensee receiving DE
E:\FR\FM\14NOP1.SGM
14NOP1
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with PROPOSALS
Federal Register / Vol. 79, No. 220 / Friday, November 14, 2014 / Proposed Rules
benefits be an entity that actually
provides service under the license. The
Commission explained that it intended
that DEs should remain primarily
providers of facilities-based service
directly to the public. That conclusion
was based on an interpretation of the
legislative history underlying the Act’s
provisions regarding unjust enrichment,
as well as the continued application of
the Commission’s controlling interest
standard and affiliation rules.
14. In the Secondary Markets Second
Report and Order, the Commission also
advised that in examining whether a
spectrum lessee would, under a
spectrum manager lease, become a
controlling interest or affiliate of the
licensee, the licensee should look to all
of the relevant circumstances, including
how large a portion of its total capacity
to provide spectrum-based services
would be leased, what involvement it
would have with the spectrum lessee as
a result of the spectrum lease, and what
relationship the two parties have with
one another apart from the lease. The
Commission concluded that a spectrum
manager lease between a designated
entity licensee and a spectrum lessee
with a prior business relationship where
substantially all of the spectrum
capacity of the licensee is to be leased
would cause the spectrum lessee to
become an attributable affiliate of the
licensee. Such affiliation would render
the licensee ineligible for designated
entity or entrepreneur benefits and,
therefore, would make such a spectrum
lease impermissible. On the other hand,
the Commission reasoned that a
spectrum manager lease involving a
small portion of the designated entity or
entrepreneur licensee’s spectrum
capacity where no relationship existed
between the licensee and spectrum
lessee apart from the lease would likely
be permissible. Situations falling
somewhere between these two examples
would have to be evaluated according to
the individual circumstances involved.
15. Subsequently in 2006, at the
behest of interested parties, including
Council Tree, the Commission released
a further notice, which sought comment
on the specific nature of the types of
relationships that should trigger the
attribution of revenues to determine
eligibility for designated entity benefits.
See Implementation of the Commercial
Spectrum Enhancement Act and
Modernization of the Commission’s
Competitive Bidding Rules and
Procedures, 71 FR 6992, Feb. 10, 2006.
For instance, Council Tree initially
proposed that the Commission should
restrict a designated entity applicant’s
‘‘material relationships,’’ including both
financial and operational agreements, in
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:06 Nov 13, 2014
Jkt 235001
order to more carefully ensure that
designated entity benefits are awarded
only to bona fide eligible entities. In the
DE Second Report and Order, the
Commission, to further protect against
unjust enrichment, departed from its
case-by-case approach and instead
adopted a bright-line test to require a
small business applicant or licensee to
automatically attribute to itself the gross
revenues of any entity with which it had
an ‘‘attributable material relationship.’’
It reasoned that an agreement that
concerns the actual use of the DE’s
spectrum capacity is one that causes the
relationship to be ripe for abuse and
creates the potential for the relationship
to impede a DE’s ability to become a
facilities-based provider, as intended by
Congress. The Commission concluded
that an applicant or licensee has an
AMR when it has one or more
agreements with any individual entity
for the lease (under either spectrum
manager or de facto transfer leasing
arrangements) or resale (including
under a wholesale arrangement) of, on
a cumulative basis, more than 25
percent of the spectrum capacity of any
individual license held by the applicant
or licensee.
16. Council Tree and others
challenged the AMR rule and other
aspects of the Commission’s 2006 Order
in the United States Court of Appeals
for the Third Circuit on the grounds that
they failed to take into account
circumstances regarding small
businesses’ access to capital, among
other things. In subsequent years, the
Office of Advocacy in the U.S. Small
Business Administration (SBA) also
expressed its belief to the Commission
that the 2006 changes to the small
business rules had ‘‘inhibited
participation by small entities and
minority businesses in recent spectrum
auctions,’’ and that the changes were
unnecessary in light of the availability
of the audit process included in the
Commission’s original auction rules. In
2010, although the court ultimately
upheld the AMR rule, it nonetheless
questioned some of the Commission’s
reasoning, noting what it termed the
Commission’s ‘‘inattention’’ to the
nature of the wireless wholesale
business. Questioning why the
Commission chose to attribute certain
relationships to achieve its stated policy
of DEs as facilities-based providers, the
court observed that wholesaling
includes an extensive provision of
service component. The court said that
it was therefore not obvious that the
Commission needed to prohibit DEs
from engaging primarily in a wholesale
business in order to prevent them from
PO 00000
Frm 00039
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
68175
simply monetizing their bidding credits
with a large carrier, ‘‘so long as [DEs] do
not sell or lease overly large quantities
of their capacity to any single lessee or
buyer.’’ Remarking that the Commission
appeared not to have acknowledged this
issue, the court commended it to the
Commission’s attention on remand.
17. Recently, in February 2014, the
Minority Media & Telecom Council
(MMTC) filed a white paper with the
Commission making nine
recommendations to facilitate the
participation of minority- and womenowned businesses in upcoming
auctions. Listed first among these is the
repeal of the AMR rule. MMTC argues
that the rule impedes the ability of small
entities to become providers of
spectrum-based service, explaining that
wholesaling and leasing arrangements
are important vehicles for small and
minority-owned businesses to build and
efficiently use capital.
18. MMTC’s White Paper argues that
‘‘over the course of fifty-six wireless
auctions during the past 20 years, the
majority of DEs that currently hold
wireless licenses are incumbent rural
telephone companies, very few DEs are
new entrants, and even fewer DEs are
(minority-owned business enterprises)
MBEs.’’ MMTC and its supporters
maintain that DE participation in
spectrum auctions dramatically
decreased after the Commission’s
adoption of its 2006 rule modifications
and claim that the results from Auctions
66 and 73 ‘‘showed a precipitous drop
in DE participation from the average
70% value of winning bids over
previous years, to only 4.0% and 2.6%
respectively.’’
19. Other parties concur with
MMTC’s concerns about the AMR rule,
arguing that the development of the
Commission’s rules and policies over
the last decade, including adoption of
the AMR rule, have significantly
hindered their ability to access capital
and largely impeded their ability to
acquire and use wireless spectrum
licenses in today’s wireless marketplace.
Parties claim that the AMR rule creates
insurmountable obstacles for new and
existing small businesses to gain access
to capital in secondary markets where
they argue small businesses can play
important roles in assuring that licensed
spectrum is effectively and efficiently
utilized. In a March 2014 request for
clarification or waiver of the AMR rule,
Grain Management, LLC described how
the rule could prevent a small, minorityowned, new-entrant lessor of spectrum
capacity on licenses acquired without
DE benefits from being eligible for such
benefits in future auctions. See Grain
Management, LLC’s Request for
E:\FR\FM\14NOP1.SGM
14NOP1
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with PROPOSALS
68176
Federal Register / Vol. 79, No. 220 / Friday, November 14, 2014 / Proposed Rules
Clarification or Waiver of 47 CFR
1.2110(b)(3)(iv)(A); Implementation of
the Commercial Spectrum Enhancement
Act and Modernization of the
Commission’s Competitive Bidding
Rules and Procedures; Expanding the
Economic and Innovation Opportunities
of Spectrum Through Incentive
Auctions; Amendment of the
Commission’s Rules with Regard to
Commercial Operations in the 1695–
1710 MHz, 1755–1780 MHz, and 2155–
2180 MHz Bands, WT Docket No. 05–
211; GN Docket Nos. 12–268 and 13–
185, Order, 29 FCC Rcd 9080 (2014).
20. Discussion. The Commission
concludes that it is appropriate to revisit
its small business eligibility rules and
evaluate whether to rebalance its
competing goals in order to provide
small businesses additional
opportunities to gain access to new
sources of capital necessary for
participation in the provision of
spectrum-based services in today’s
marketplace, while guarding against
unjust enrichment of ineligible entities.
Chief among the actions that the
Commission takes in the Competitive
Bidding NPRM is its proposal to repeal
the AMR rule and to re-examine the
related decade-old policy underlying it.
In lieu of the bright-line test of the AMR
rule, the Commission proposes a twopronged approach to evaluate an entity’s
eligibility for small business benefits.
This approach would use its existing
controlling interest and affiliation
standards to determine what revenues
are attributable to an applicant based
upon a rigorous review of all relevant
relationships and agreements, which
will ensure that the small business
makes independent decisions about its
business operation. Alternatively, the
Commission also seeks comment on
whether it should retain the policy but
modify the AMR rule with some other
attribution threshold to determine an
applicant’s eligibility for small business
benefits.
21. Using long standing principles of
control and affiliation, the Commission
proposes to safeguard small business
benefits by attributing the revenues of
any entity that has the ability to control,
or potentially control, an applicant’s
business venture. The Commission’s
existing attribution rules examine the
extent to which a small business may
combine its efforts, property, money,
skill and knowledge with another.
Further, where there is an agreement to
share profits/losses proportionate to
each party’s contribution to the business
operation, the existing rules consider
these issues as a factor in whether to
attribute that party to the applicant as
its affiliate. Because the Commission’s
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:06 Nov 13, 2014
Jkt 235001
proposals should allow small businesses
greater flexibility to engage in business
ventures that include increased forms of
leasing and other spectrum use
arrangements, the Commission
anticipates that the combined effect of
the proposals—by allowing a small
business greater flexibility to adopt a
more individualized business model for
each license it holds—should increase
the potential sources of revenue for the
small business and potentially decrease
the likelihood that it would be subject
to undue influence by any particular
user of a single license. The
Commission’s proposed approach
would also ensure that a licensee retains
control of all licenses for which it seeks
bidding credits, while providing greater
flexibility in potential uses for any
licenses acquired without such benefits.
The Commission seeks comment on this
proposal and asks commenters to
specifically address how and why a
small business may be more or less
likely to be subject to undue influence
by a user of its spectrum under this
approach. Additionally, the
Commission proposes to modify the
language of 47 CFR 1.9020 to make clear
how the secondary market rules apply
to DE lessors, which should provide
greater flexibility to small businesses in
how they choose to use their spectrum.
The Commission also seeks comment on
whether any corresponding changes
may be warranted in its unjust
enrichment rules to ensure that small
business bidding credits are extended
only to qualifying small businesses.
22. The AMR rule and the policy that
spurred its adoption were intended to
prevent unjust enrichment by
establishing safeguards to ensure that
entities ineligible for small business
incentives could not circumvent the
Commission’s rules by obtaining those
benefits indirectly, through their
relationships with eligible entities. The
Commission based its decisions, in large
measure, on legislative history
suggesting that anti-trafficking
restrictions and unjust enrichment
payment obligations were needed to
deter participation in the licensing
process by those who have no intention
of offering service to the public. For
example, in the Secondary Markets
Second Report and Order, the
Commission relied on the legislative
history in rejecting a commenter’s
argument that ‘‘[t]here [was] no reason
to believe that Congress intended to
limit designated entities to only one
form of participation in the spectrum
market—construction and operation of a
facilities-based network.’’ In adopting
the AMR rule, the Commission
PO 00000
Frm 00040
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
reaffirmed that interpretation of the
legislative history, concluding that the
adoption of the AMR rule, along with
other modifications, was necessary to
strengthen its implementation of
Congress’s directives with regard to DEs
and to ensure that, in accordance with
the intent of Congress, every recipient of
its DE benefits is an entity that uses its
licenses to directly provide facilitiesbased telecommunications services for
the benefit of the public.
23. Yet, in the Commission’s attempts
to safeguard small business benefits
from unjust enrichment, it appears that
the Commission’s policy and
corresponding rule modifications may
have had the unintended consequence
of hindering the Commission’s ability to
satisfy its statutory goal of promoting
opportunities for wireless entry by small
businesses. Moreover, the Commission
notes that the statute does not
specifically state, nor does the House
Report make clear, that Congress
intended to require that ‘‘offering
service to the public’’ be defined only as
DEs directly providing facilities-based
telecommunications services for the
benefit of the public. The Commission
may have placed undue weight on
language from the House Report, given
all of the various factors that the actual
text of 47 CFR 309(j) gives the
Commission the discretion to balance.
In interpreting statutes, analysis of the
statutory text, aided by established
principles of interpretation, controls.
24. While the policy of requiring
primarily the direct provision of
facilities-based service by a small
business seeking bidding credits is one
way to protect against unjust
enrichment, the Commission tentatively
concludes that it is not the only way to
ensure that benefits are provided solely
to those entities that Congress intended.
The Commission also recognizes that
the AMR rule, which was adopted to
further that policy, may inhibit the
highest and best use of spectrum by
preventing small businesses that lack
access to traditional sources of capital
from being able to acquire alternative
revenue streams through leasing and
other spectrum use arrangements, even
in circumstances where they retain
control over their business venture.
MMTC argues that there has been a
documented decline in DE participation
and success at auction following the
adoption of the Commission’s rule
changes in 2006, based on the relative
value of licenses won by DEs compared
to non-DEs. While the Commission
notes that the relative value of licenses
won at auction is only one measure to
gauge success of the small business
program and that there are other
E:\FR\FM\14NOP1.SGM
14NOP1
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with PROPOSALS
Federal Register / Vol. 79, No. 220 / Friday, November 14, 2014 / Proposed Rules
relevant factors to consider in assessing
whether the Commission has met its
statutory obligations for small
businesses, the Commission nonetheless
concurs that over the last decade small
businesses have faced various increased
difficulties in becoming wireless
licensees.
25. The Commission contemplates
that a different approach may be more
effective in balancing its competing
goals of affording small businesses
reasonable flexibility to obtain the
capital necessary to participate in the
provision of spectrum-based services
and effectively preventing the unjust
enrichment of ineligible entities.
Inasmuch as Congress has granted the
Commission the discretion to weigh the
varying objectives of section 309(j), the
Commission proposes rule
modifications that, if adopted, could
offer a more balanced approach for
achieving its statutory directives. The
Commission therefore proposes to
repeal the AMR rule and evaluate small
business eligibility in a manner that
could provide DEs with greater
opportunities to participate in the
provision of spectrum-based services,
including through secondary market
transactions. The Commission
anticipates that this, in turn, will help
DEs gain access to capital by enabling
leasing and other spectrum use
arrangements. Allowing more DEs and
small businesses to participate in
spectrum leases and other spectrum use
agreements will also promote the
Commission’s goals of promoting more
efficient and dynamic use of the
important spectrum resource through
secondary market spectrum
transactions.
26. The Commission seeks comment
on this proposal to repeal the AMR rule,
and its tentative conclusions regarding
its need to re-evaluate its small business
policy. Should the Commission
discontinue its policy requiring small
businesses seeking bidding credits to
provide primarily direct, facilities-based
service on each individual license?
Would this proposal better promote
Congress’s intent for small businesses?
Would the proposal to eliminate this
policy and to repeal the AMR rule have
the unintended effect of providing
ineligible entities with access to
discounted spectrum?
27. In a mature wireless industry
where leasing and other spectrum use
arrangements may be important tools to
enable wireless providers to raise
capital and participate at auction, is it
appropriate to provide small businesses
seeking bidding credits with greater
flexibility to enter into such spectrum
use arrangements? Should the
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:06 Nov 13, 2014
Jkt 235001
Commission consider an alternative
spectrum capacity use limit for a brightline attribution test, and if so what is the
appropriate percentage and what
spectrum use arrangements should it
include? Would eliminating the policy
that small businesses provide primarily
facilities-based service with each
individual license increase or decrease
the risk of unjust enrichment to
ineligible entities and/or the
warehousing of spectrum? What
safeguards should the Commission
consider to ensure that bidding credits
are extended only to qualifying small
businesses, as Congress intended?
Alternatively, should the Commission
retain the AMR rule and the related
policy that small businesses primarily
provide facilities-based service, but
stipulate that neither would kick in for
a set number of years? This approach
might provide small businesses with an
opportunity to raise capital early in the
license term but still require that they
eventually become primarily facilitiesbased providers of service when the
AMR rule kicks in. Commenters should
address when the AMR rule and the
related policy regarding facilities-based
service should kick in and how
construction build-out requirements
should be measured. Commenters
should also address whether the
Commission’s proposed shift in policy
would continue to allow auctions to
award licenses to those entities that
value the spectrum most highly, which
fosters the Commission’s ability to
accomplish Congress’s multi-faceted
policy objectives. Will rebalancing the
Commission’s approach to Congress’s
goals provide adequate safeguards
against unjust enrichment to ensure that
bidding credits are awarded only to
qualifying small businesses?
28. Proposed Standard for Evaluating
Small Business Eligibility. The
Commission proposes a more focused
approach to evaluate small business
eligibility that looks at who controls, or
has the potential to control, the
applicant and any spectrum acquired
with the use of small business benefits.
Specifically, the Commission proposes
to apply a two-pronged test using its
existing controlling interest and
affiliation rules to determine: (1)
Whether an applicant meets the
applicable small business size standard,
and (2) whether it retains control over
the spectrum associated with the
licenses for which it seeks small
business benefits. This approach will
allow the Commission to separate its
review of those who control, or have the
power to control, the small business
applicant’s business venture, and are
PO 00000
Frm 00041
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
68177
therefore attributable for purposes of
determining eligibility, from those that
use (and may control) its spectrum
capacity, which would affect the small
business’s ability to retain its benefits
with respect to any particular license.
Consistent with the Commission’s
existing controlling interest and
affiliation rules under 47 CFR
1.2110(c)(2)(ii)(H)–(I), it will attribute
the revenues of those entities or
individuals that determine or
significantly influence the nature or
types of services offered by the small
business, the terms upon which such
services are offered, and the prices
charged for such services. The
Commission’s proposals would expand
the types of services the small business
might offer as part of its overall business
venture, but would not alter how the
Commission carefully monitors those
that have the ability to control, or
potentially control, the applicant or
licensee and its business venture. The
Commission seeks comment on these
specific proposals.
29. The first prong would evaluate
whether an applicant meets the
applicable small business size standard
and is therefore eligible for benefits. To
evaluate small business eligibility, the
Commission proposes to apply its
existing controlling interest standard
and affiliation rules to determine
whether an entity should be attributable
based on whether that entity has de jure
or de facto control of, or is affiliated
with, the applicant’s overall business
venture. De jure control is typically
evidenced by the holding of greater than
50 percent of the voting stock of a
corporation or, in the case of a
partnership, general partnership
interests. De facto control is determined
on a case-by-case basis to determine
whether the licensee has actual control
over its business venture. Thus,
pursuant to 47 CFR 1.2110 and
consistent with the Commission’s
current analysis, under its proposal,
control and affiliation may arise
through, among other things, ownership
interests, voting interests, or the terms
of any agreements that create a
controlling, or potentially controlling,
relationship over the applicant’s
business venture. The Commission
therefore notes that its proposal to
eliminate the policy that small
businesses seeking benefits primarily
provide facilities-based service does not
alter the rules that require it to consider
whether facilities-sharing and other
agreements confer control of or create
affiliation with the applicant. The
proposal also does not alter the general
standard by which the Commission
E:\FR\FM\14NOP1.SGM
14NOP1
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with PROPOSALS
68178
Federal Register / Vol. 79, No. 220 / Friday, November 14, 2014 / Proposed Rules
evaluates whether a licensee has ceded
de facto control and effected an
unauthorized transfer of control of its
spectrum authorization to a third party.
30. The Commission’s continued
careful and targeted examination of
these issues will allow it to ensure that
a small business applicant has the
independent ability to direct its
decision making regarding its overall
business venture and how its licenses
are used to offer service to the public.
Moreover, those claiming small business
benefits will continue to be bound by
the Commission’s existing rules
regarding control and attribution, which
should be familiar to all existing and
future Commission licensees. By
providing small businesses with greater
opportunities to access revenue streams
through leasing and other spectrum use
agreements, the Commission anticipates
that they will have more flexibility to
employ business models that suit their
individual needs and therefore will be
less likely to be influenced by deeppocketed investors or parties with
which they have a spectrum use
agreement. Furthermore, this approach
recognizes the Commission’s earlier
conclusion in the Secondary Markets
proceeding that the mere existence of a
spectrum use agreement between a
small business and another party does
not, without more, cause the other party
to become an attributable interest holder
in the applicant. This approach,
coupled with the Commission’s
proposed departure from the policy of
requiring small businesses to provide
primarily facilities-based service
directly to the public with each of its
licenses, should allow small businesses
to gain access to capital and better
enable them to participate in auctions
and in the provision of spectrum-based
services, so long as the terms of any
spectrum use agreement do not confer
control or create an affiliation that
would lead to attribution of
disqualifying revenues. Will this
approach promote long-term
investment, market participation and
competition in the wireless industry by
small businesses?
31. Once the first prong has been met,
the Commission would evaluate
eligibility under the second prong.
Under the second prong, the
Commission proposes to determine an
entity’s eligibility to retain small
business benefits on a license-by-license
basis, based on whether the entity has
maintained de jure and de facto control
of the license. Under this proposed
license-by-license approach, an entity
will not necessarily lose its eligibility
for all current and future small business
benefits solely because of a decision
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:06 Nov 13, 2014
Jkt 235001
associated with any particular license.
Instead, while a small business might
incur unjust enrichment obligations if it
relinquishes de jure or de facto control
of any particular license for which it
claimed benefits, so long as the
revenues of its attributable interest
holders (i.e., the DE’s affiliates, its
controlling interests, and the affiliates of
its controlling interests) continue to
qualify under the relevant small
business size standard, it could still
retain its eligibility to retain current and
future benefits on existing and future
licenses. In other words, an applicant
need not be eligible for small business
benefits on each of the licenses it holds
in order to demonstrate its overall
eligibility for such benefits. For
instance, if a small business chooses to
permissibly relinquish benefits,
incurring any applicable unjust
enrichment obligation, and transfer de
facto control of a license through a de
facto transfer lease, that lease will not
necessarily make the lessee an
attributable interest holder in the
applicant or cause the applicant to
become ineligible for other small
business benefits it might have or want
to acquire.
32. The Commission stresses that
small businesses, like all its licensees,
remain subject to its rules to prevent
unauthorized transfers of control of
their license authorizations pursuant to
section 310(d) of the Act. Accordingly,
if a small business seeking benefits
executes a spectrum use agreement that
does not comply with the Commission’s
relevant standard of de facto control, it
will be subject to unjust enrichment
obligations for the benefits associated
with that particular license. If the terms
of that spectrum use agreement go so far
as to confer control of, or the potential
to control, the small business’s overall
business venture, the business could
risk the attribution of revenues, which
could render it ineligible for all current
and future small business benefits on all
licenses. Except where the leasing
standard of de facto control applies
under the secondary market rules, the
criteria of Intermountain Microwave and
Ellis Thompson will continue to apply
to any Commission licensee, including
a small business, for purposes of
assessing whether it can demonstrate
that it retains de facto control of its
business venture and spectrum
authorization. See Applications for
Microwave Transfers to Teleprompter
Approved with Warning; Non-broadcast
and General Action Report No. 1142,
Public Notice (by the Commission en
banc), 12 FCC 2d 559, 559–60 (1963)
(Intermountain Microwave); Ellis
PO 00000
Frm 00042
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
Thompson Corporation, 60 FR 1776,
Jan. 5, 1995. Small businesses will,
however, be free under this proposal
from the added policy requirement
regarding the extent to which it must
use each individual spectrum license for
the provision of facilities-based service
in order to retain eligibility for small
business benefits.
33. The Commission seeks comment
on its proposed two-pronged approach
to evaluate attribution and establish
eligibility for small business benefits.
Will this proposal provide small
businesses with the flexibility necessary
to participate in an evolving wireless
marketplace? Does the absence of a
bright-line attribution standard hinder
an applicant’s ability to assess its
eligibility for small business benefits?
Will the Commission’s proposed
approach allow it to safeguard the
benefits it awards and prevent ineligible
entities from obtaining benefits
indirectly, through arrangements with
eligible small businesses? Should the
Commission take additional steps to
assure that ineligible entities cannot
exercise undue influence over a small
business, or will its proposed approach
empower small businesses to make their
own decisions with respect to the
highest and best use of each of their
licenses without risking the undue
influence of their investors or spectrum
users? For instance, should the
Commission, in considering whether the
user’s revenues should be attributable to
the small business applicant, consider
any limits on the amount of its spectrum
capacity a small business seeking
benefits can allow a third party to use,
even where such use is otherwise
permissible under Commission rules
and the agreement on its own does not
create a controlling interest or affiliation
in the applicant’s business venture?
34. Should the Commission limit the
ability of a small business seeking
benefits to lease all of its spectrum
capacity or should the Commission
allow it to be primarily engaged in the
business of leasing provided that it
complies with small business eligibility
rules? Would allowing a small business
seeking benefits to lease 100 percent of
its spectrum capacity on any individual
license, and/or on all of its licenses,
increase the potential of the unjust
enrichment of ineligible entities?
Commenters should address how that
risk increases or decreases based on the
amount of spectrum capacity that may
be leased. Should the Commission be
concerned that a small business leasing
large quantities of its spectrum capacity
to a single user has allowed another
entity to receive the benefit of its
bidding credits?
E:\FR\FM\14NOP1.SGM
14NOP1
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with PROPOSALS
Federal Register / Vol. 79, No. 220 / Friday, November 14, 2014 / Proposed Rules
35. Should there be a standard by
which the Commission should
automatically attribute the gross
revenues of an entity with which a
small business seeking benefits has
spectrum use agreements if it has such
agreements with a single entity in
numerous markets? How should the
Commission view small businesses that
have multiple financial and/or
operational arrangements with another
licensee or entity where the agreements
do not otherwise create a controlling
interest or affiliation with the small
business? Should the existence of such
multiple agreements create a rebuttable
presumption of affiliation similar to the
kinship affiliation rule, or does the
Commission’s existing rule of
‘‘affiliation through contractual
relationships’’ already adequately guard
against a third party acquiring control,
or the potential to control, the small
business through such agreements? For
instance, should the Commission permit
a small business seeking benefits to
have a combination of capital
investments, loan, marketing,
management and leasing agreements
with another Commission licensee
without attributing the gross revenues of
that entity to the small business? Is
there a combination of agreements that
should cause more concern in assessing
small business benefit eligibility, and
should any combination of agreements
with a single party create a rebuttable
presumption of attribution or an
ineligibility for small business benefits?
Are there any specific types of
agreements that are more likely to
confer control or undue influence of the
small business seeking benefits that
should cause the Commission to
automatically attribute the gross
revenues of the entity to the small
business or render the small business
ineligible for benefits?
36. Do the Commission’s proposals
provide small business applicants with
sufficient flexibility to access capital,
compete in auctions, and participate in
new and innovative ways in the
provision of service in the wireless
marketplace while retaining their
benefits? Do the Commission’s
proposals make it more or less likely
that a small business will be unduly
influenced by the entities with which it
engages in spectrum use agreements?
Commenters opposing these proposals
should indicate specific concerns.
Commenters supporting these proposals
should offer any other suggestions the
Commission should consider to revise
its rules and reform its small business
policies. To what extent do the
Commission’s proposed changes for
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:06 Nov 13, 2014
Jkt 235001
small business eligibility positively or
negatively affect auction revenues? To
what extent do the Commission’s
proposals appropriately balance its
competing statutory obligations in
section 309(j) of the Act?
37. Proposed Standard for Evaluating
DE Leasing. The Commission also
proposes to modify the language of 47
CFR 1.9020 to comport with the
Commission’s proposed approach to
assessing small business eligibility.
Specifically, the Commission proposes
to make clear that DEs may fully benefit
from the same de facto control standard
for spectrum manager leasing in the
Commission’s secondary market rules as
non-DE lessors.
38. In developing its regulatory
scheme for leasing generally, the
Commission determined that section
310(d) of the Act did not require the
continued application of the facilitiesbased Intermountain Microwave six-part
test that had, since 1963, been applied
to determine whether a licensee was
exercising the requisite level of de facto
control over its licensed operations.
Instead, the Commission adopted a
revised de facto control standard for
leasing arrangements for purposes of
applying the requirements of section
310(d). Under the revised standard, a
spectrum manager lease does not
constitute a transfer of de facto control
so long as the licensee (1) maintains an
active, ongoing oversight role in
ensuring that the lessee complies with
Commission rules and policies; (2)
retains responsibility for all interactions
with the Commission required under
the license related to the use of the
leased spectrum; and (3) remains
primarily and directly accountable to
the Commission for any lessee violation
of these policies and rules.
39. While the Commission nominally
applied the new standard to all
licensees, it explained that DEs would
be required to retain their eligibility
under the traditional facilities-focused
de facto control standard of 47 CFR
1.2110 and Intermountain Microwave.
Thus, the Commission stated that small
businesses could engage in leasing only
to the extent that doing so would not
affect their eligibility for benefits.
Further, it required that a licensee
receiving DE benefits be an entity that
actually provides service under the
license. As explained above, the
Commission expressed concern that
unless it continued to require DEs to
remain engaged primarily in the
provision of facilities-based services to
the public it would run the risk that
small business incentives, particularly
bidding credits, would indirectly benefit
entities that would not qualify for those
PO 00000
Frm 00043
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
68179
incentives in the primary market. To
that end, the Commission specified that
small businesses could not retain their
benefits if they made spectrum leasing
their primary business.
40. Consistent with the Commission’s
proposed revisions to assessing small
business eligibility, including the
elimination of the requirement that
small businesses primarily provide
facilities-based service on each license
they hold, the Commission proposes a
modification to its spectrum manager
leasing rule. Specifically, the
Commission proposes to modify the
language in 47 CFR 1.9020(d)(4) to
remove the conflicting reference to the
control standard of 47 CFR 1.2110 in
order to make clear that small business
lessors are fully subject to the same de
facto control standard for spectrum
manager leasing that applies to all other
licensees. This modification should
clarify that 47 CFR 1.9010 alone defines
whether a licensee, including a small
business, retains de facto control of the
spectrum that it leases to a spectrum
lessee in the context of spectrum
manager leasing. This proposal does not
alter the fact that small businesses must
remain eligible for benefits under 47
CFR 1.2110. Instead, the proposed
modification clarifies that one de facto
standard applies to determine whether
the licensee has de facto control of the
spectrum in the context of a spectrum
manager lease (i.e., 47 CFR 1.9010), and
the other applies to determine whether
a third party has control, or the
potential to control, the licensee and its
business venture for the purposes of
attribution of revenues (i.e., 47 CFR
1.2110). In sum, the Commission’s
proposal departs from the traditional
Intermountain Microwave facilitiesfocused de facto control standard with
regard to an individual spectrum lease
agreement for a particular license. As
long as the small business: (1) Maintains
an active, ongoing oversight role in
ensuring that the lessee complies with
Commission rules and policies; (2)
retains responsibility for all interactions
with the Commission required under
the license related to the use of the
leased spectrum; and (3) remains
primarily and directly accountable to
the Commission for any lessee violation
of these policies and rules, it will be
considered to maintain de facto control
of its spectrum for the purposes of that
spectrum manager lease. Spectrum
manager leasing applications will
continue to be evaluated to determine
whether control of, or affiliation with,
the small business applicant and its
overall business venture has arisen
through any the terms of the leasing
E:\FR\FM\14NOP1.SGM
14NOP1
68180
Federal Register / Vol. 79, No. 220 / Friday, November 14, 2014 / Proposed Rules
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with PROPOSALS
agreement that might lead to attribution
and result in unjust enrichment under
47 CFR 1.2110.
41. When the Commission adopted 47
CFR 1.9010, it noted that a licensee’s
continued control over the licensed use
of spectrum lies at the heart of what it
means to retain the license and the
rights thereunder and that it could no
longer generally assume that the
licensee must perform the non-licensed
activities identified in Intermountain
Microwave in order to conclude that the
licensee has retained its license and all
rights thereunder. The Commission
proposes that its modification will make
clear that this conclusion applies
equally to all licensees. Are there any
reasons why the Commission should
retain its existing language in 47 CFR
1.9020(d)(4)? Should the Commission
consider limiting the amount of
spectrum a small business can lease to
a single entity under 47 CFR 1.9020, in
order to ensure that the small business
retains control over its business venture
as required in 47 CFR 1.2110?
Commenters opposing the
Commission’s proposal should offer
alternative suggestions for how it could
allow small businesses to play a larger
role in secondary market transactions.
B. Unjust Enrichment
42. The integrity of the small business
benefit program depends on ensuring
that only entities eligible for benefits
receive them. To safeguard against
abuse, the Commission has long relied
on unjust enrichment provisions, which
require a small business to pay back the
benefits it accrued where appropriate,
and careful vigilance in approving
applications and transactions. With the
proposals set forth in the Competitive
Bidding NPRM, the Commission
anticipates that these provisions will be
as important as ever and that strong
enforcement of the provisions is critical.
The Commission therefore seeks
comment on whether any changes are
appropriate to strengthen its unjust
enrichment rules and how best the
Commission can continue to scrutinize
applications and proposed transactions
to ensure that only eligible entities
receive benefits, while not undermining
the Act’s directive to ensure that DEs are
given the opportunity to participate in
the provision of spectrum-based
services.
43. Pursuant to 47 CFR 1.2111(b),
small businesses are obligated to make
unjust enrichment payments if they
seek, inter alia, to assign or transfer
control of licenses to a non-eligible
party, for a period of up to five years
from the initial issuance of the license.
In rebalancing the Commission’s policy
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:06 Nov 13, 2014
Jkt 235001
objectives to provide small businesses
greater opportunities to participate at
auction and in the provision of
spectrum-based services, it remains
focused on its responsibility to ensure
that benefits are provided only to
qualifying entities.
44. The Commission therefore invites
comment on whether its existing five
year unjust enrichment payment
schedule continues to provide a
sufficient safeguard to ensure that
benefits are provided only to qualifying
entities. Commenters should be specific
about whether there is a need to adjust
its current five year unjust enrichment
repayment schedule, and the
appropriate length and reimbursement
percentages for any repayment schedule
revisions. If commenters support a
different repayment period or different
percentages for the repayment schedule,
they should be specific about why their
suggested approach would better meet
its goals and balance the Commission’s
statutory objectives.
45. Specifically, the Commission also
seeks comment on whether it should
consider adopting a 10 year unjust
enrichment repayment schedule for
licenses acquired with bidding credits,
including its benefits and costs.
Extending the length of the unjust
enrichment repayment schedule to 10
years may help deter speculation and
prevent spectrum warehousing. At the
same time, extending the length of the
unjust enrichment repayment schedule
could restrict small businesses’ access to
capital, which could limit their ability
to participate in the provision of
spectrum-based services, contrary to the
Commission’s underlying goals in this
proceeding. How does the length of the
repayment schedule affect a small
business’s capital fundraising and
business planning efforts? Are there
lessons the Commission can draw from
based on parties’ experience raising
capital when the 10 year unjust
enrichment period was in place from
2006 until 2010? If the Commission
repeals the AMR rule as proposed and
also modifies the unjust enrichment
rules, what would be the combined
effect on the ability of a small business
to raise capital and participate at
auction and in the provision of service,
particularly when compared to the
existing rule?
46. Are there other unjust enrichment
provisions that the Commission should
consider? For example, should the
Commission require full reimbursement,
plus interest, if a small business loses its
eligibility prior to meeting the
construction requirements applicable at
the end of the license term?
Commenters should discuss how such
PO 00000
Frm 00044
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
an approach would impact the
Commission’s interest in protecting
against unjust enrichment, while
ensuring that small businesses have
access to capital to participate at auction
and in the provision of service. Is a
different reimbursement percentage
(something less than 100 percent)
preferable? Are other safeguards
sufficient to protect the Commission’s
interests regarding unjust enrichment?
47. The Commission seeks comment
on whether it may grant small
businesses greater flexibility to
participate in the provision of spectrumbased services, as it has proposed, while
also ensuring that only those entities
Congress intended have access to
benefits. The Commission asks
commenters to address how the unjust
enrichment rules affect their ability to
secure and retain capital and whether
its rules require other further
modifications to safeguard the award of
small business benefits. By granting
small businesses greater regulatory
flexibility to demonstrate eligibility,
does the Commission increase or
decrease the likelihood that non-eligible
entities can assert undue influence over
a small business’s decision making for
its business venture and its utilization
of licenses to participate in the
provision of spectrum-based services?
48. The Commission also seeks
comment on how other government
programs ensure that only an intended
class of recipients receive benefits that
are awarded to eligible entities. Are
there other government programs that
have greater safeguards than the
Commission currently employs? How
do other government agencies and small
business benefit programs prevent abuse
and guard against unjust enrichment of
ineligible entities? Commenters should
be specific about any analogies that can
be drawn between the Commission’s
small business benefits and similar
benefits awarded by other agencies and
programs.
49. The Commission’s efforts to
provide increased flexibility to small
businesses must be balanced with
vigilant enforcement to ensure that only
bona fide small businesses receive
benefits. The Commission has a strong
interest in ensuring that truthful and
accurate information is available to the
Commission and the public for purposes
of implementing and enforcing policies
it finds to be in the public interest. Such
information is imperative to the
Commission’s ability to safeguard the
benefits it awards and to prevent unjust
enrichment. To the extent the
Commission modifies rules regarding its
small business benefits, it will remain
vigilant in undertaking careful review of
E:\FR\FM\14NOP1.SGM
14NOP1
Federal Register / Vol. 79, No. 220 / Friday, November 14, 2014 / Proposed Rules
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with PROPOSALS
all applications of those seeking to
acquire or retain bidding credits to
ensure that the gross revenues of all
parties that control, or have the
potential to control, the applicant are
properly attributed in compliance with
its controlling interest and affiliation
rules. The Commission emphasizes that
it will remain focused on ensuring that
an applicant’s certifications for
eligibility comport with the actual terms
of its agreements with relevant parties.
In so doing, the Commission expects
that it can properly execute its statutory
responsibility to continue to prevent
unjust enrichment of ineligible entities.
C. Bidding Credits
50. The Commission also takes a fresh
look at the primary way that it facilitates
participation by small businesses at
auction through its bidding credit
program. The Commission notes that the
generally applicable small business
definitions and corresponding bidding
preferences were adopted in 1997 and
finds that it is appropriate to revisit
whether these standards have kept pace
with an evolving wireless marketplace.
Toward that end, the Commission
proposes to increase the general size
standards, measured by gross revenues,
for purposes of determining an entity’s
eligibility for a bidding preference. The
Commission also proposes to continue
its practice of evaluating which small
business definitions will apply on a
service-by-service basis, based upon
associated capital requirements for a
particular service. In addition, the
Commission seeks comment on whether
to increase the bidding credit
percentages applicable to associated
small business categories. Finally, the
Commission seeks comment on its
ability to consider bidding preferences
for other types of DEs, entities that serve
unserved/underserved areas or areas
with persistent poverty, as well as
persons and entities that have overcome
disadvantages. The Commission expects
that the questions raised here will
provide a meaningful opportunity to
evaluate whether its bidding credit
program continues to achieve its
objectives. The Commission seeks
concrete, specific, data-driven feedback
by commenters to facilitate its review.
The Commission invites commenters to
suggest other creative ideas that would
promote its statutory objectives, but it
emphasizes that for any such proposals
it is imperative to provide ample
supporting evidence.
51. An auction applicant may claim
eligibility for a bidding credit when
filing a short-form application. The
Commission’s short-form application is
the first part of its two-phased auction
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:06 Nov 13, 2014
Jkt 235001
application process. In the first phase,
any party desiring to participate in an
auction must file a streamlined shortform application in which it certifies
under penalty of perjury as to its
qualifications to participate in a
Commission auction. In its review of the
short-form applications, Commission
staff presume the information and
certifications contained in the shortform applications are true unless they
are incomplete, internally inconsistent
or contradicted by information in the
Commission’s records. Eligibility to
participate in bidding is based on
information in an applicant’s short-form
application and its certifications, and on
its upfront payment. In the second
phase of the Commission’s application
process, a winning bidder files a more
comprehensive long-form (FCC Form
601) application. The long-form
application is subject to more extensive
review and is the basis for any
determination that a winning bidder is
qualified to hold a Commission license
and for the award of any claimed
bidding credit.
1. Small Business Bidding Credits
52. Background. Bidding credits
operate as a percentage discount on the
winning bid amounts of a qualifying
small business. By making the
acquisition of spectrum licenses more
affordable for new and existing small
businesses, bidding credits facilitate
their access to needed capital. The
Commission establishes eligibility for
bidding credits for each auctionable
service, adopting one or more
definitions of the small businesses that
will be eligible. The Commission’s small
business definitions have been based on
an applicant’s average annual gross
revenues over a three-year period. In
establishing the gross revenues
thresholds for the small business
definitions to be applied to a specific
service, the Commission takes into
account the capital requirements and
other characteristics of the particular
service. In order to qualify for a small
business bidding credit an applicant
must demonstrate that its gross
revenues, in combination with those of
its ‘‘attributable’’ interest holders, fall
below the applicable financial caps.
53. The Commission’s rules provide a
schedule of small business definitions
and corresponding bidding credits. In
adopting bidding credits for a particular
service, the Commission has found that
the use of the small business size
standards and credits set forth in the
part 1 schedule provides consistency
and predictability for small businesses.
Section 1.2110(f) sets forth three tiers of
bidding credits: (1) A 35 percent
PO 00000
Frm 00045
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
68181
bidding credit for businesses with
average annual gross revenues for the
preceding three years not exceeding $3
million; (2) A 25 percent bidding credit
for businesses with average annual gross
revenues for the preceding three years
not exceeding $15 million; and (3) A 15
percent bidding credit for businesses
with average annual gross revenues for
the preceding three years not exceeding
$40 million.
54. Discussion. The Commission
proposes to increase the gross revenues
thresholds defining the three tiers of
small businesses in the part 1 schedule
by which the Commission provides the
corresponding available bidding credits
and seeks comment on alternatives. The
Commission also proposes to continue
its practice of deciding which small
business definitions will apply on a
service-by-service basis depending on
the capital requirements of the
particular spectrum to be auctioned. In
addition, the Commission seeks
comment on whether the bidding credit
percentages that apply to these small
business definitions should be
increased.
55. Since the inception of the
Commission’s DE program, and
particularly in the past decade, the
evolution of the mobile wireless
marketplace from mobile voice to
mobile broadband has increased the
demands on wireless networks and the
need for access to spectrum, heightening
the capital-intensive nature of the
industry. Moreover, the number of small
and regional mobile wireless service
providers has significantly decreased,
though regional and local service
providers continue to offer consumers
additional choices in the areas they
serve. In light of these changes and
statutory goals, the Commission seeks
comment on how it should reconsider
definitions of what constitutes a small
business in the wireless industry.
56. The Commission proposes to
increase the gross revenues thresholds
in its part 1 schedule to reflect the
changing nature of the wireless
industry, including the overall increase
in the size of wireless networks and the
increase in capital costs to deploy them.
The Commission notes that these
changes have resulted in an increase in
the size of the wireless service providers
that can be considered to be ‘‘small’’
relative to the large nationwide
providers. By proposing adjustments to
the Commission’s small business size
standards, it aims to promote the
effective participation of small
businesses in auctions and in the
provision of spectrum-based services.
57. In considering how much to adjust
the gross revenues thresholds, the
E:\FR\FM\14NOP1.SGM
14NOP1
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with PROPOSALS
68182
Federal Register / Vol. 79, No. 220 / Friday, November 14, 2014 / Proposed Rules
Commission proposes to use the price
index for the U.S. Gross Domestic
Product (GDP price index) published by
the U.S. Department of Commerce
(Commerce). The Commission notes that
the SBA, as part of its size standards
review, recently used the GDP price
index to adjust its receipts-based
industry size standards. In particular,
the Commission proposes to adjust the
current gross revenues thresholds with
the percentage change in the GDP price
index between 1997 and 2013. The
indices are available on Commerce’s
Bureau of Economic Analysis Web site,
under Tables 1.1.4 and 1.1.15, at https://
www.bea.gov/itable.
58. The Commission believes that the
GDP price index may reflect certain
industry trends and a relevant range of
economic activity better than the
available wireless industry price indices
published by the Bureau of Labor and
Statistics (BLS). In barely a decade, the
shift from a voice-centric to a datacentric wireless industry has seen
mobile broadband data services grow
from their nascent stage to become a
significant share of the industry’s
market revenues. However, the available
wireless industry price indices may
under represent broadband data services
because the indices are based on voicecentric definitions of service plans.
Moreover, broadband data plans are not
treated as a separate category in the
indices, and the BLS description of the
indices is unclear about how the advent
of mobile broadband services has been
factored into the voice-centric consumer
and producer prices indices that were
introduced in 1997 and 1999,
respectively. Furthermore, the wireless
industry consumer and producer price
indices may exclude goods and inputs
that are relevant for the range of
economic activity involved in the
provision of wireless services.
Therefore, the Commission proposes to
use the broader GDP price index. The
GDP price index increased by 36.4
percent from 1997 to 2013. Based on
this 36.4 percent increase, the
Commission proposes new gross
revenues thresholds that are obtained by
multiplying the current thresholds by
1.364 and rounding to the nearest
million. Specifically, the Commission
proposes to revise the standardized
schedule in 47 CFR 1.2110(f) as follows:
(1) Businesses with average annual gross
revenues for the preceding three years
not exceeding $4 million would be
eligible for a 35 percent bidding credit;
(2) Businesses with average annual gross
revenues for the preceding three years
not exceeding $20 million would be
eligible for a 25 percent bidding credit;
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:06 Nov 13, 2014
Jkt 235001
and (3) Businesses with average annual
gross revenues for the preceding three
years not exceeding $55 million would
be eligible for a 15 percent bidding
credit.
59. The Commission seeks comment
on its proposal to adjust the current
gross revenues thresholds in its small
business size standards using the GDP
price index. Is there a different price
index that better reflects industry
developments and the relevant range of
economic activity? Is there an
alternative method for setting new gross
revenues thresholds that does not
require adjusting the current gross
revenues thresholds with a price index?
60. The Commission tentatively
concludes that its proposed gross
revenues thresholds better reflect the
larger size of wireless networks today,
and thus expect that they will preserve
the effectiveness of the Commission’s
bidding credit program in the current
mobile wireless marketplace. Consumer
demand for widely available mobile
broadband services has increased
providers’ need for additional capital to
acquire spectrum and deploy service.
This trend is reflected in the changing
structure of the industry. By increasing
the gross revenues thresholds that
define small businesses and thereby
making bidding credits available to a
larger number of entities, the
Commission seeks to facilitate a higher
rate of participation by entities that
might otherwise find it difficult to
obtain the necessary capital to
participate at auction. The Commission
seeks comment on whether the
proposed increases in the revenues
thresholds are likely to increase the
percentage of entities that will benefit
from its small business bidding credits,
by providing better access to capital and
enabling them to seek access to the
spectrum necessary to meet consumer
demand for mobile broadband services.
At the same time, to further the
statutory objectives of the auction
program, the Commission must adopt
revenues thresholds that will avoid
including firms that have adequate
access to financing for spectrum based
on their revenue levels. The
Commission therefore seeks to avoid
setting eligibility for bidding credits at
a level that is over inclusive, which
would defeat the purpose of the bidding
credits and undermine the statutory
objectives of the program. Any new
thresholds the Commission adopts
should provide economic opportunity to
small businesses, while maintaining
good economic incentives for small
businesses to seek diverse forms of
financing for spectrum.
PO 00000
Frm 00046
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
61. The Commission seeks comment
on this proposal. Specifically, how have
capital costs, construction costs, and
administrative costs faced by wireless
providers changed since the mid-1990s?
Have the costs of spectrum usage rights
increased significantly since the early
stages of the Commission’s auction
program such that it is more difficult for
small businesses to acquire wireless
spectrum today?
62. Commenters who agree that the
industry’s evolution warrants new
definitions for small businesses should
discuss what gross revenues thresholds
are appropriate for defining small
businesses in the wireless context.
Commenters should explain their
methodologies for deriving alternative
thresholds and should supply
supporting data or justifications for the
Commission’s use in evaluating and
applying such methodologies. If
commenters do not provide data on
wireless providers’ gross revenues, what
alternative factors should the
Commission consider in determining
what constitutes a ‘‘small business’’ in
today’s wireless marketplace?
63. The Commission also seeks
comment on whether to adopt a small
business size standard based on criteria
other than gross revenues. As the
Commission recently noted in the
AWS–3 proceeding, in first adopting
gross revenues-based small business
size standards for eligibility for DE
benefits, the Commission rejected the
SBA’s employee-based business size
standard for cellular or other wireless
telecommunications entities as a means
to qualify as a DE. The Commission
concluded that such a definition would
be too inclusive and would allow many
large telecommunications firms to take
advantage of preferences not intended
for them. The Commission notes that
according to census data, if it adopted
the SBA’s small business employeebased size standard for cellular or other
wireless telecommunications entities
(i.e., 1,500 or fewer employees) more
than 96 percent of wireless companies
would be considered small businesses.
The Commission therefore tentatively
concludes not to reconsider its
conclusion that the SBA’s employeebased definition is too inclusive for the
purposes of establishing DE eligibility.
64. In addition, the Commission asks
commenters to consider whether it
should increase the bidding credit
percentages (i.e., discount amounts)
currently available to small businesses
in 47 CFR 1.2110(f). Should the
Commission use the existing bidding
credit percentages, but apply them to
higher gross revenues thresholds?
Should the Commission add additional
E:\FR\FM\14NOP1.SGM
14NOP1
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with PROPOSALS
Federal Register / Vol. 79, No. 220 / Friday, November 14, 2014 / Proposed Rules
small business definitions and
associated tiers of bidding credits above
or below the tiers proposed above?
Commenters supporting additional tiers
of bidding credits should propose a
corresponding gross revenues threshold
for each additional tier. Commenters
supporting changes to the existing
bidding credit percentages in the
Commission’s part 1 rules should
explain the basis for their proposals and
provide any supporting data for the
Commission’s use in evaluating
potential changes to the part 1 schedule.
Commenters should also address
whether increases in the bidding credit
percentages are necessary if the
Commission adopts its proposal to
modify the gross revenues thresholds for
its small business definitions since that
will have the effect of increasing the
level of bidding credit a substantial
number of small businesses would
receive compared to its current rules.
For instance, by increasing the revenues
thresholds, entities previously eligible
for small business bidding credits under
the current schedule may become
eligible for a higher bidding credit tier
under the proposed amended schedule,
and entities that previously exceeded
the highest revenue threshold may
become eligible. Similarly, bidders that
previously exceeded the thresholds as a
result of attributable revenues under the
AMR rule may fall below the thresholds,
and thus become eligible for small
business bidding credits, if the AMR
rule is eliminated as proposed in the
Competitive Bidding NPRM.
65. Further, the Commission proposes
to continue its practice of soliciting
comment on the appropriate small
business size standards in connection
with establishing rules for any
particular service. As the Commission
has done in the past and pursuant to 47
CFR 1.2110(c)(1), it would continue to
take into consideration the
characteristics and capital requirements
of each service. The Commission seeks
comment on this proposal.
Alternatively, should the Commission
utilize all three small business
definitions and bidding credit tiers in
every service? Under this approach, the
Commission would make bidding
credits available to any business that
meets one of the small business
definitions without engaging in an
assessment of the likely capital
requirements of the specific service for
which licenses are being offered. What
are the advantages and disadvantages of
this alternative approach? If the
Commission continues to adopt small
business definitions on a service-byservice basis, are there other factors that
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:06 Nov 13, 2014
Jkt 235001
it should consider in determining which
small business definition to apply to a
specific service? Alternatively, if the
Commission adopts its proposed
modifications to the AMR and small
business size standards, should it
consider reducing the level of bidding
credits it awards? Commenters should
provide specific suggestions on how the
Commission should weigh its proposals
collectively.
66. The Commission also seeks
comment on whether any revisions it
adopts in this proceeding to its part 1
schedule of small business size
standards and associated bidding credit
percentage levels should apply to the
specific small business definitions and
bidding credit percentages the
Commission has previously adopted for
specific services, and, if so, how such
revisions would be implemented. In
particular, the Commission proposes
that any new rules adopted in this
proceeding would apply to the 600 MHz
band spectrum licenses to be offered in
the BIA. In the BIA proceeding, the
Commission adopted a 15 percent
bidding credit for small businesses
(defined as entities with average annual
gross revenues for the preceding three
years not exceeding $40 million) and a
25 percent bidding credit for very small
businesses (defined as entities with
average annual gross revenues for the
preceding three years not exceeding $15
million). Consistent with the increased
gross revenues thresholds the
Commission proposes for the
standardized schedule in its part 1
competitive bidding rules, the
Commission also proposes to increase
the gross revenues thresholds associated
with the 15 and 25 percent bidding
credits adopted for the 600 MHz band.
That is, for the 600 MHz band, the
Commission proposes to provide a
bidding credit of 25 percent for
businesses with average gross revenues
for the preceding three years not
exceeding $20 million and a bidding
credit of 15 percent for businesses with
average gross revenues for the preceding
three years not exceeding $55 million.
The Commission seeks comment on this
proposal. In addition, the Commission
seeks comment on whether to adopt a
third tier of small business bidding
credits for the 600 MHz band that would
provide a 35 percent bidding credit to
businesses with average gross revenues
for the preceding three years not
exceeding $4 million. If the Commission
re-auctions licenses for existing
services, should the previously adopted
service-specific small business
definitions and bidding credit
percentages be revised for those services
PO 00000
Frm 00047
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
68183
to reflect any changes to its part 1
schedule in 47 CFR 1.2110(f)(2)?
2. Other Bidding Preferences
67. The Commission’s primary
method of fulfilling its statutory
mandate regarding DEs has been to offer
auction bidding credits to small
business applicants. Periodically,
however, interested parties have
suggested that the Commission offer
bidding preferences to entities based on
criteria other than business size. As the
Commission has explained in the past,
its ability to implement suggestions to
target bidding credits to other types of
entities is constrained by both its
statutory authority and standards of
judicial review. The Commission seeks
comment on these suggestions and asks
commenters to specifically address the
statutory authority and judicial scrutiny
issues that may limit its ability to
entertain recommendations to alter the
focus of its current bidding preferences.
a. Minority- and Women-Owned
Businesses and Rural Telephone
Companies
68. Section 309(j)(4)(D) of the Act
directs the Commission to consider the
use of bidding preferences to ensure that
small businesses, rural telephone
companies, and businesses owned by
members of minority groups and women
are given the opportunity to participate
in the provision of spectrum-based
services. The Commission seeks
comment on whether the current small
business provisions are sufficient to
promote participation by businesses
owned by minorities and women, as
well as rural telephone companies. To
the extent that commenters propose
additional provisions to ensure
participation by minority-owned or
women-owned businesses, they should
address how such provisions could be
crafted to meet the relevant standards of
judicial review. The Commission asks
commenters advocating for the adoption
of rural bidding credits to supply data
demonstrating that rural telephone
companies lack access to capital or face
barriers to capital formation similar to
those faced by other DEs.
b. Unserved/Underserved Areas and
Persistent Poverty Preferences
69. The Commission seeks comment
on whether it should extend bidding
credits to winning bidders that deploy
facilities and provide service to
unserved or underserved areas. If the
Commission adopts bidding credits for
service to unserved or underserved
areas what criteria should it consider to
determine if an area is unserved or
underserved? Should any unserved/
E:\FR\FM\14NOP1.SGM
14NOP1
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with PROPOSALS
68184
Federal Register / Vol. 79, No. 220 / Friday, November 14, 2014 / Proposed Rules
underserved area bidding credits be
available in all areas lacking service,
only in rural areas, or only in
persistently poor counties? As required
of providers awarded universal service
funds through the Mobility Fund Phase
I auctions, should a wireless provider
awarded an unserved/underserved
bidding credit be required to provide a
certain level of service (e.g., 3G or 4G)
by a certain time frame (e.g., two or
three years) in order to retain the benefit
of the bidding credit?
70. The Commission also seeks
comment on whether the Commission
should offer a bidding credit to winning
bidders that will use their licensed
spectrum to deploy service to persistent
poverty counties. As defined by the
Department of Agriculture’s Economic
Research Service (ERS), a county is
persistently poor if 20 percent or more
of its population was living in poverty
over the last 30 years. According to the
ERS, ‘‘there are currently 353
persistently poor counties in the United
States (comprising 11.2 percent of all
U.S. counties).’’ The ERS further
explains that ‘‘[t]he large majority (301
or 85.3 percent) of the persistentpoverty counties are nonmetro,
accounting for 15.2 percent of all
nonmetro counties. Persistent poverty
also demonstrates a strong regional
pattern, with nearly 84 percent of
persistent-poverty counties in the
South, comprising of more than 20
percent of all counties in the region.’’
The ERS information is available on the
ERS Web site under ‘‘Geography of
Poverty,’’ at https://www.ers.usda.gov/
topics/rural-economy-population/ruralpoverty-well-being/geography-ofpoverty.aspx. If the Commission adopts
such a bidding credit, should it impose
strict performance requirements on
providers awarded bidding credits for
licenses covering persistent poverty
counties similar to those required of
winning bidders awarded Tribal land
bidding credits? Should this type of
bidding credit only apply to licenses
covering persistent poverty counties
that are only served by two or fewer
wireless service providers?
71. If the Commission adopts
unserved/underserved area and/or
persistent poverty county bidding
credits, should the bidding credits be
available only to small businesses and/
or other DEs, or to any applicant? How
would the Commission calculate the
credit amount where the unserved or
underserved area or targeted counties
cover a portion of a license area? Should
the bidding credit be applied to the total
amount of the winning bid for a license,
or should it be applied to a portion of
the winning bid based on a percentage
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:06 Nov 13, 2014
Jkt 235001
of population or square miles of the
license area covered by the unserved/
underserved area or identified counties
or some other metric? What size bidding
credit would be appropriate for either
an unserved/underserved area bidding
credit or a persistent poverty county
bidding credit? If an applicant qualifies
for both bidding credits, should the
Commission limit the amount of the
combined credit? Similarly, if an
applicant qualifies for one of these
credits in addition to a small business
bidding credit, should the credits be
cumulative and, if so, should there be a
limit on the amount of the aggregate
bidding credit provided? Should any
limit be an amount greater than the
maximum small business bidding credit
to allow DEs eligible for the highest
bidding credit tier to receive an
increased benefit for also providing
service to an unserved/underserved area
and/or persistent poverty county?
Commenters supporting cumulative
bidding credits should provide data or
support justifying the need for higher
bidding credits in unserved/
underserved and/or persistent poverty
areas. Alternatively, are issues relating
to lack of deployment or low levels of
deployment of wireless services in rural
and poor areas better addressed through
means other than the Commission’s
bidding credit program, such as through
service-specific build-out requirements
or reliance on incentives through its
Mobility Fund and other universal
service programs?
72. The Commission seeks comment
on its authority to implement these
types of bidding preferences. The
Commission notes that it has previously
implemented bidding credits based on
other criteria than business size in order
to facilitate service to Tribal lands. See
In the Matter of Extending Wireless
Telecommunications Services to Tribal
Lands, 65 FR 47366, May 2, 2003 (Tribal
Lands Report and Order). In that
proceeding, the Commission found that
the objectives and requirements of
section 309(j) of the Act, which the
Commission must consider in designing
competitive bidding systems, authorized
it to grant bidding credits targeted
specifically to entities that commit to
bringing much needed wireless
telecommunications services to Tribal
lands. Specifically, in the Tribal Lands
Report and Order, the Commission
found that Tribal Land bidding credits
further the objective of section
309(j)(3)(A) to ensure ‘‘the development
and rapid deployment of new
technologies, products, and services for
the benefit of the public, including
those residing in rural areas. . . .’’ and
PO 00000
Frm 00048
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
the objective of section 309(j)(3)(D) of
promoting ‘‘efficient and intensive use
of the electromagnetic spectrum.’’ The
Commission also found that there is no
indication in section 309(j)(4)(D) or in
its legislative history that the
Commission’s authority to award
bidding preferences is limited to small
businesses, rural telephone companies,
and businesses owned by members of
minority groups and women. As such,
the Commission tentatively concludes
that section 309(j) of the Act similarly
authorizes the Commission to provide
bidding credits for service to unserved/
underserved areas and persistent
poverty counties. The Commission
seeks comment on its tentative
conclusion.
c. Overcoming Disadvantages Preference
73. In view of renewed interest raised
in the BIA proceeding, the Commission
also seeks additional comment on the
2010 Recommendation by the FCC’s
Advisory Committee on Diversity for
Communications in the Digital Age
(2010 Recommendation) to implement a
bidding preference for persons or
entities who have overcome substantial
disadvantage (referred to herein as an
overcoming disadvantages preference or
ODP). In that 2010 Recommendation,
the Committee proposed that the
Commission should provide an auction
bidding credit for otherwise qualified
persons or entities that have overcome
substantial disadvantages, to allow them
to compete on equal footing with other
applicants. The Committee stated that
an ODP would provide a fair
opportunity for highly qualified
applicants to compete for spectrum
licenses, thereby expanding the pool of
eligible bidders in an auction. The 2010
Recommendation is available at https://
www.fcc.gov/DiversityFAC/
meeting101410.html. The Media and
Wireless Telecommunications Bureaus
subsequently issued a public notice
seeking comment on additional
information that would be helpful in
evaluating whether and how to pursue
the Committee’s proposal: The
Overcoming Disadvantage Preference
Public Notice, 75 FR 81274, Dec. 27,
2010.
74. Commenters should specifically
address the Commission’s statutory
authority to adopt such a preference and
how such a preference could be crafted
to meet the relevant standards of
judicial review. Would a preference for
those who have overcome a substantial
disadvantage be subject to a ‘‘rational
basis’’ constitutional standard, as the
2010 Recommendation indicates?
Additionally, the Commission seeks
detailed comment on how the
E:\FR\FM\14NOP1.SGM
14NOP1
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with PROPOSALS
Federal Register / Vol. 79, No. 220 / Friday, November 14, 2014 / Proposed Rules
preference would provide additional
opportunities not available under the
current bidding credit program,
particularly if the current program is
amended as proposed in the
Competitive Bidding NPRM.
75. The Commission also asks for
input on how it might systematically
collect and maintain data in order to
implement and administer an ODP.
What legal basis does it have to collect
data, and what precise data would the
Commission need to support such a
proposal?
76. The Commission asks commenters
to address how eligibility for an ODP
could be demonstrated, providing
specific information as to what
definitions of disadvantages could
qualify individuals or entities for the
preference. How would it measure when
any particular disadvantage had been
overcome? The 2010 Recommendation
provides a non-exhaustive list that
includes disadvantages such as physical
disabilities or psychological disorders
that rendered professional or business
advancement substantially more
difficult than for most individuals. How
could the Commission avoid subjective
determinations and implement and
apply an ODP on a neutral basis? The
Commission asks commenters to discuss
how it could establish eligibility for the
preference objectively. How could the
Commission render eligibility
determinations for an ODP without
appearing arbitrary? How could it
safeguard any such benefits to ensure
they are awarded only to eligible
persons or entities?
77. The Commission also seeks
detailed comment on how it could
administer an ODP. Commenters should
identify the costs and benefits
associated with such a program,
addressing matters such as how reviews
would be conducted, and the nature of
the demonstration applicants seeking a
preference would be required to make,
as well as how individualized
evaluation for the preference would be
incorporated into a time-sensitive shortform application process or whether
alternatives such as pre-qualification
would be necessary.
78. As acknowledged by the Advisory
Committee, its ODP proposal raises a
number of issues that need to be refined
and resolved in order to design and
implement such a preference, and
comment provided to date has not
provided sufficient basis or justification
for doing so. Therefore, commenters that
continue to support the adoption of an
ODP are encouraged to provide as
detailed and specific suggestions as
possible regarding the Commission’s
authority to establish the ODP and its
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:06 Nov 13, 2014
Jkt 235001
objectives in doing so, as well as
eligibility for, and administration of, the
preference, to assist the Commission in
determining a legal, neutral, and
efficient way in which it could
implement an ODP. Alternatively, the
Commission asks commenters to
consider whether the proposals the
Commission has made to amend its
existing DE program would obviate the
need for the adoption of such a
preference.
D. DE Reporting Requirements
79. Background. Section 1.2110(n)
requires DE licensees to file an annual
report with the Commission that
includes, at a minimum, a list and
summaries of all agreements and
arrangements, extant or proposed, that
relate to eligibility for DE benefits. The
list must include the parties (including
affiliates, controlling interests, and
affiliates of controlling interests) to each
agreement or arrangement, as well as the
dates on which the parties entered into
each agreement or arrangement. DEs are
required to file a report for each of their
licenses no later than, and up to five
business days before, the anniversary of
the date of license grant.
80. Discussion. The Commission
proposes to repeal this reporting
requirement. The information DEs are
required to include in their annual
reports is duplicative of information
that they provide in their auction and
license applications. See 47 CFR
1.2110(j), 1.2112(b)(2)(iii). In addition,
before entering into leases or other
agreements that might affect their
eligibility, DEs must seek Commission
approval and must list and summarize
those agreements, including the parties
to and the dates of the agreements. See
47 CFR 1.2114. Moreover, for licensees
with multiple auction licenses, each
having a different grant date, the burden
of the annual reporting requirement is
exacerbated by the obligation to file
multiple reports each year. For these
reasons, the Commission tentatively
concludes that the value of the
information provided in these annual
reports may no longer outweigh the
reporting burden that they impose on
DEs.
81. The Commission seeks comment
on its proposal. In particular,
commenters are invited to address
whether there are any benefits to
retaining the annual reporting
requirement that the Commission has
failed to consider. Does this reporting
requirement in any way help the
Commission identify agreements
between parties relating to small
business eligibility that might otherwise
escape attention? Commenters should
PO 00000
Frm 00049
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
68185
specifically address how other rules
render this reporting requirement
duplicative and how other rules
adequately ensure that the Commission
is aware of all agreements between
parties relating to small business
eligibility. Will relieving DEs of this
annual reporting requirement reduce
their regulatory burdens to any
measurable degree? Without this
reporting requirement, will the
Commission continue to have the
necessary tools to safeguard DE benefits
from unjustly enriching ineligible
entities? If the Commission adopts this
proposal to eliminate this annual
reporting requirement, should the
Commission amend the requirement in
47 CFR 1.2114 that a small business list
and summarize all existing agreements
to provide context each time it reports
a new eligibility event?
E. MMTC’s White Paper Requests
82. Background. In February 2014,
MMTC submitted a White Paper
detailing several policy
recommendations to advance minority
and women spectrum license
ownership. In addition to requesting the
elimination of the AMR, an increase in
bidding credits, and a substantive
review of proposed DE rules, the White
Paper requests Commission action in
the following areas: (1) Reinstitute select
DE-only closed spectrum auctions; (2)
Incorporate diversity and inclusion in
the Commission’s public interest
analysis of mergers and acquisitions
(M&As) and secondary market spectrum
transactions; (3) Conduct ongoing
recordkeeping of DE performance; (4)
Complete the Adarand Studies,
updating the section 257 studies
released in 2000; (5) Regularize
procedural requirements; and (6)
Support increased funding for and
statutory amendments regarding the
Telecommunications Development
Fund. The Commission notes that
MMTC’s above request with respect to
‘‘ongoing recordkeeping of DE
performance’’ refers to retaining specific
information about minority- and
woman-owned business enterprise
bidders, in addition to the small
business status.
83. Discussion. The Commission seeks
comment on the proposals that are not
otherwise addressed in the NPRM, and
to the extent that they relate to its
competitive bidding rules. The
Commission observes that certain
proposals appear to be outside the scope
of this proceeding and others may not
be needed in light of other changes
proposed herein. Toward that end, the
Commission tentatively concludes that
the following MMTC proposals are
E:\FR\FM\14NOP1.SGM
14NOP1
68186
Federal Register / Vol. 79, No. 220 / Friday, November 14, 2014 / Proposed Rules
outside the scope of this proceeding,
which is focused on its competitive
bidding rules, and thus will not be
addressed here: (1) Incorporating
diversity and inclusion in the
Commission’s public interest analysis of
mergers and acquisitions and secondary
market spectrum transactions; and (2)
supporting increased funding for and
statutory amendments regarding the
Telecommunications Development
Fund. The Commission seeks comment
on MMTC’s additional requests,
including discussion regarding the
relative costs and benefits of each
proposal. Are the proposals that the
Commission describes elsewhere in the
NPRM, including the elimination of the
AMR rule, sufficient to address the
concerns identified by MMTC regarding
the participation of businesses owned
by members of minority groups and
women in the provision of spectrumbased services?
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with PROPOSALS
III. Other Part 1 Considerations
84. In advance of an auction that
could hold historic potential for
interested applicants to acquire licenses
for below-1-GHz spectrum, the
Commission also explores the need for
other revisions to its general part 1
competitive bidding rules to improve
the transparency and efficiency of the
auction and its processes. The
Commission proposes changes to its
former defaulter rule that seek to
balance commenters’ concerns that the
current rules are overly broad with its
continued need to ensure that auction
bidders are financially reliable. The
Commission also proposes to codify an
existing competitive bidding procedure
that prohibits the same individual or
entity from filing more than one shortform application to participate in an
auction and it proposes a new rule that
would prevent entities that are
exclusively controlled by a single
individual or set of individuals from
becoming qualified to bid on the basis
of more than one short-form application
in a specific auction. Both proposals
seek to prevent duplicative filings and
to avert anticompetitive bidding
behavior at auction. Regarding the joint
bidding rules, the Commission seeks
comment on, among other issues, its
tentative conclusions that it would be in
the public interest to retain the current
rules governing joint bidding
arrangements among non-nationwide
providers and to prohibit joint bidding
arrangements among nationwide
providers. Additionally, the
Commission provides notice of its
intention to resolve long standing
petitions for reconsideration and
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:06 Nov 13, 2014
Jkt 235001
proposes necessary clean-up revisions
to its part 1 competitive bidding rules.
A. Former Defaulter Rule
85. Background. Each potential
participant in a Commission auction
must certify on its pre-auction shortform application whether or not the
applicant, its affiliates, its controlling
interests, and the affiliates of its
controlling interests have ever been in
default on any Commission license or
have ever been delinquent on any nontax debt owed to any federal agency.
With the exception of the Commission’s
upcoming auction for AWS–3 licenses
(Auction 97) for which it recently
granted a limited blanket waiver, an
applicant is considered to be a ‘‘former
defaulter’’ if the applicant, including
any of its affiliates, its controlling
interests, or any of the affiliates of its
controlling interests, has defaulted on
any Commission license or been
delinquent on any non-tax debt owed to
any federal agency, but has since
remedied all such defaults and cured all
of its outstanding non-tax
delinquencies. Former defaulters are
eligible to bid in a Commission auction
provided they are otherwise qualified,
but are required to pay upfront
payments that are 50 percent more than
the normal upfront payment amounts.
86. In the Part 1 Fifth Report and
Order, the ‘‘former defaulter’’ policies
were incorporated into the
Commission’s part 1 general
competitive bidding rules. See
Amendment of Part 1 of the
Commission’s Rules—Competitive
Bidding Procedures, 65 FR 52323, Aug.
29, 2000 (Part 1 Fifth Report and Order).
The Commission reasoned that the
integrity of the auctions program and
the licensing process dictates requiring
a more stringent financial showing from
applicants with a poor federal financial
track record. Thus, while cure of an
outstanding federal default or
delinquency enables the former
defaulter to participate in an auction,
the rules require the former defaulter to
make a larger upfront payment. Other
than in the recent waiver for Auction
97, the former defaulter rule has been
applied without any limitation as to age
or scope of an applicant’s prior default
or delinquency.
87. On August 29, 2014, in response
to unopposed requests from wireless
industry parties, the Commission
granted a limited blanket waiver to
narrow the circumstances under which
an applicant for Auction 97 would be
considered a former defaulter and
required to submit a larger upfront
payment to qualify to bid. The
Commission concluded that the
PO 00000
Frm 00050
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
underlying purpose of the upfront
payment and former defaulter rules
would not be served by their broad
application in the AWS–3 auction, and
that a limited waiver served the public
interest. Specifically, for Auction 97, the
Commission waived the former
defaulter rule for applicants to exclude
any cured default or delinquency for
which any of the following criteria were
met: (1) The notice of the final payment
deadline or delinquency was received
more than seven years before the
Auction 97 short-form application
deadline of September 12, 2014; (2) the
amount of the default or delinquency
falls below $100,000; (3) the default or
delinquency was paid within two
quarters (i.e., 6 months) after receiving
the notice of the final payment deadline
or delinquency; or (4) the default or
delinquency was the subject of a legal
or arbitration proceeding that was cured
upon resolution of the proceeding. See
Petition of DIRECTV Group, Inc. and
EchoStar LLC (collectively, DIRECTV/
EchoStar) for Expedited Rulemaking to
Amend Section 1.2105(a)(2)(xi) and
1.2106(a) of the Commission’s Rules
and/or for Interim Condition Waiver;
Auction of Advanced Wireless Services
(AWS–3) Licenses Scheduled for
November 13, 2014 (Auction 97), RM–
11395; AU Docket No. 14–78, Order,
FCC 14–130, para. 1 (rel. Aug. 29, 2014)
(Auction 97 Former Defaulter Waiver
Order). Pursuant to the Auction 97
Former Defaulter Waiver Order, only
applicants that have had a cured default
or delinquency that falls outside of
these exclusions would have to certify
to being a ‘‘former defaulter’’ and
submit a larger upfront payment in
Auction 97. The Auction 97 Former
Defaulter Waiver Order noted that the
Commission’s limited grant of the
blanket waiver for Auction 97 was
without prejudice to its further
examination and disposition, based on a
complete record, of the issues
surrounding the former defaulter rule
through a rulemaking proceeding.
88. Discussion. Although the former
defaulter rule serves an important and
necessary function to ensure that
bidders are capable of meeting their
financial commitments, the Commission
tentatively concludes that the rule may
be too far-reaching and impose
unnecessary costs and burdens on
auction participants. The Commission
proposes a more tailored approach by
balancing concerns that the current
application of the rule is overbroad with
its continued need to ensure that
auction bidders are financially reliable.
The Commission seeks comment on
revising the rule to narrow the scope of
E:\FR\FM\14NOP1.SGM
14NOP1
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with PROPOSALS
Federal Register / Vol. 79, No. 220 / Friday, November 14, 2014 / Proposed Rules
the defaults and delinquencies that will
be considered in determining whether
or not an auction participant is a former
defaulter. Specifically, the Commission
proposes to exclude any cured default
on any Commission license or
delinquency on any non-tax debt owed
to any federal agency for which any of
the following criteria are met: (1) The
notice of the final payment deadline or
delinquency was received more than
seven years before the relevant shortform application deadline; (2) the
default or delinquency amounted to less
than $100,000; (3) the default or
delinquency was paid within two
quarters (i.e., 6 months) after receiving
the notice of the final payment deadline
or delinquency; or (4) the default or
delinquency was the subject of a legal
or arbitration proceeding that was cured
upon resolution of the proceeding. The
Commission seeks comment on limiting
the individuals and entities that an
applicant must consider when
determining its status as a former
defaulter.
89. In offering these proposals to limit
the former defaulter rule, the
Commission keeps in mind the
underlying purposes of the upfront
payment rule generally, and the
increased upfront payment required of
former defaulters. The Commission
typically requires auction participants
to provide upfront payments in order to
qualify to bid in an auction. Upfront
payments help prevent frivolous or
insincere bidding and provide the
Commission with a source of funds from
which to collect payments owed at the
close of auction. In adopting an upfront
payment requirement, the Commission
also recognized that it was balancing the
goal of encouraging bidders to submit
serious, qualified bids with the desire to
simplify the bidding process and
minimize implementation costs that
will be imposed on bidders. The
original former defaulter rule appeared
in the Commission’s part 24 Broadband
PCS rules in the wake of financial
difficulties of participants in the C
Block auctions. The Commission
subsequently incorporated the part 24
former defaulter policies into the part 1
general competitive bidding rules,
noting that the rule’s purpose was to
preserve the integrity of the auction
process and ensure that bidders are
capable of meeting their financial
commitments to the Commission. As the
Commission noted in the Auction 97
Former Defaulter Waiver Order, in the
14 years since that Commission action,
its auctions program has matured and
the mobile wireless industry has grown
into a major segment of the nation’s
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:06 Nov 13, 2014
Jkt 235001
economy. Accordingly, the Commission
considers in the Competitive Bidding
NPRM whether the current broad rule
continues to strike the right balance to
promote the goals of its upfront
payment and former defaulter rule.
90. The parties that requested waiver
of the former defaulter rule also suggest
that the Commission modify the rule.
For instance, in their petition,
DIRECTV/EchoStar argue that, as
currently written, the former defaulter
rule applies too broadly to effectively
advance the Commission’s goal of
ensuring that auction bidders are
financially reliable. In their joint filing,
CCA, CEA, CTIA and NTCA (the Four
Associations) mirror that sentiment and
suggest that the scope of the rule is
unnecessary to achieve its purpose,
particularly when the former defaults or
delinquencies are in a relatively small
amount or were cured years prior. These
parties offer a variety of ways to limit
the scope of the former defaulter
inquiry, but all consistently contend
that the rule is unnecessarily broad to
serve its underlying purpose. The
Commission seeks comment on its
specific proposals to narrow the scope
of the defaults and delinquencies that
would trigger an auction applicant’s
former defaulter status and asks
commenters to address whether, if such
proposals are adopted, the Commission
can still promote the important
protective functions of its upfront
payment and former defaulter rules.
91. Parties urge first that prior
delinquencies and defaults more than a
certain number of years old should be
excluded from the scope of the former
defaulter rule. In the Auction 97 Former
Defaulter Waiver Order, the
Commission excluded from
consideration under the former
defaulter rule any cured default or
delinquency for which the notice of the
final payment deadline or delinquency
was received more than seven years
before the Auction 97 short-form
application deadline of September 12,
2014. The Commission concluded that
the rule’s current unlimited time period
may capture former defaults and
delinquencies that have lost their
relevance to a bidder’s current
capability to meet its financial
commitments to the Commission, and
thus may no longer warrant a larger
upfront payment for Auction 97.
Initially, advocates seeking a more
limited time frame for the rule’s
application argued that a three year
period would correspond to certain
Federal tax statute of limitations. In
seeking a waiver for Auction 97, CCA,
CTIA and NTCA (the Three
Associations) suggested that the
PO 00000
Frm 00051
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
68187
Commission should define former
defaulters to include only those
applicants who have received notice of
defaults or delinquencies within seven
years before the Auction 97 short-form
application deadline. In the Auction 97
Former Defaulter Waiver Order, the
Commission noted that while federal tax
laws have a three-year statute of
limitations to determine if certain forms
of additional tax are owed, the period of
limitations to determine whether
income was under-reported is six years
and the Internal Revenue Service has a
seven-year period to review a claim for
a loss from worthless securities or a bad
debt deduction. Likewise, the
Commission acknowledged that the Fair
Credit Reporting Act limits many types
of reporting by consumer credit agencies
for a period of seven years. In light of
these longer federal limitations periods,
the Commission tentatively concludes
that the purposes of the upfront
payment and former defaulter rules may
be furthered more precisely if the
Commission excludes any cured default
on a Commission license or a
delinquency on a non-tax debt owed to
a federal agency where the notice of the
final payment deadline or delinquency
was received more than seven years
before the short-form application
deadline. In doing so, the Commission
notes that the determination of a notice
of a final payment deadline or
delinquency depends on the origin of
the federal non-tax debt giving rise to a
default or delinquency and such notice
may be express or implied. To the
extent that the rules providing for
payment of a specific federal debt
permit payment after an original
payment deadline accompanied by late
fee(s), such debts would not be in
default or delinquent for purposes of
applying the former defaulter rules until
after the late payment deadline. For the
purposes of the certifications required
on a short-form auction application,
notice provided by Commission staff
assessing a default payment arising out
of a default on a winning bid constitutes
notice of the final payment deadline
with respect to a default on a
Commission license. The Commission
seeks comment on all aspects of this
proposal—the number of years specified
(seven), the triggering event (upon
receipt of the notice of the final
payment deadline or delinquency), and
the point at which the counting of the
age of the triggering event is cut off (the
short-form application deadline). To the
extent commenters advocate a different
length of time, an alternate triggering
event, or another way of calculating
how long ago the triggering event
E:\FR\FM\14NOP1.SGM
14NOP1
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with PROPOSALS
68188
Federal Register / Vol. 79, No. 220 / Friday, November 14, 2014 / Proposed Rules
occurred, the Commission urges them to
be specific as to why their proposal is
more appropriate given the policies
behind its rule. Should the length of
time it took the defaulter to cure the
debt, or how recently the cure occurred,
be a factor?
92. Those favoring modification of the
rule also suggest excluding former
defaults or delinquencies that fall below
a certain amount. The Auction 97
Former Defaulter Waiver Order
excluded from consideration under the
former defaulter rule for Auction 97 any
former default or delinquency for which
the amount of the resolved debt or
delinquency fell below $100,000. Parties
initially suggested excluding defaults or
delinquencies of what they defined as
de minimis in nature, and specifically
suggested that the Commission should
ignore any former default or
delinquency totaling less than the lesser
of $100,000 or 0.1 percent of the average
annual revenues of the applicant, as
computed by its competitive bidding
rules. The Three Associations later
suggested that the Commission exclude
from the definition of former defaulter
any cured defaults on a Commission
license or delinquencies on a non-tax
debt owed to a federal agency in an
amount of less than $100,000. In the
Auction 97 Former Defaulter Waiver
Order, the Commission noted the
$100,000 amount is used in other
contexts to distinguish between less
significant or material issues and more
significant ones and the Commission
concluded that for the purposes of
Auction 97, requiring a larger upfront
payment based on any cured default or
delinquency that is less than $100,000
could discourage participation in
Auction 97 without appreciably
ameliorating the risk of bidder defaults,
and thereby undermine the underlying
purposes of its upfront payment and
former defaulter rules.
93. For clarity and efficiency of the
administration of the former defaulter
rule from both the Commission’s and
applicants’ perspectives, the
Commission now proposes to adopt for
future auctions generally the same
bright-line standard established in the
Auction 97 Former Defaulter Waiver
Order that would exclude from the rule
any former default on a Commission
license or delinquency on a non-tax
debt owed to a federal agency where the
amount of the resolved debt falls below
$100,000. The Commission tentatively
concludes that such an exclusion will
simplify the application process and
minimize implementation costs
imposed on applicants by excluding
former defaults and delinquencies for
which consideration is no longer
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:06 Nov 13, 2014
Jkt 235001
necessary to ensure bidders in a more
mature wireless industry submit
serious, qualified bids. The $100,000
threshold aligns with Commission
precedent and is used in other contexts
to determine the materiality or
significance of various issues. See
Auction 97 Former Defaulter Waiver
Order at para. 18. If commenters
disagree with the amount proposed, the
Commission encourages them to
provide specific examples of how
former defaults or delinquencies of a
different amount would better reflect an
auction applicant’s financial reliability.
The Commission also seeks comment on
whether its proposal adequately weighs
its need to consider debts of a serious
nature that are indicative of a bidder’s
poor federal track record with the
burdens faced by many applicants in
complying with the current rule, which
might be considered open-ended in
scope.
94. To address situations where, due
to incorrect addresses, delivery
problems, or internal issues, applicants
may not timely pay obligations, but cure
such debts when discovered, the Three
Associations also contend that the
Commission should for the purposes of
the former defaulter rule exclude certain
additional resolved debts. For Auction
97 applicants, the Commission waived
the former defaulter rule to exclude any
cured default or delinquency where the
debt was paid within two quarters (i.e.,
6 months) after receiving the notice of
final payment deadline or delinquency.
There, the Commission concluded that
the prompt cure of such a default or
delinquency sufficiently demonstrated
an applicant’s financial wherewithal,
that therefore it was unnecessary to
require a larger upfront payment from
the applicant, and that a waiver under
such circumstances served the public
interest by encouraging prompt payment
of debts owed to the government. The
Commission now proposes to modify
the former defaulter rule generally to
exclude a default or delinquency that
was paid within two quarters (i.e., 6
months) after receiving the notice of the
final payment deadline or delinquency
for the same reasons articulated in the
Auction 97 Former Defaulter Waiver
Order. The Commission seeks comment
on whether this exclusion will allow it
to appropriately balance the
practicalities that may affect the
applicants’ ability to timely resolve their
debts with the need to ensure that
bidders are capable of meeting their
financial commitments to the
Commission. The Commission also
invites commenters to address whether
payment within some other time period
PO 00000
Frm 00052
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
might better strike that balance, and
whether receipt of the notice of the final
payment deadline or delinquency is the
appropriate triggering event for this
exclusion.
95. Similarly, the Three Associations
also suggest for the purposes of
modifying the former defaulter rule that
an applicant should not be considered
to be in default if any debt is the subject
of a good faith dispute or a pending
legal or arbitration proceeding. In the
Auction 97 Former Defaulter Waiver
Order, the Commission included this
suggestion in part, and concluded that
where the default or delinquency was
the subject of a legal or arbitration
proceeding and was cured upon
resolution of the proceeding, an
applicant has demonstrated sufficient
financial credibility so that it was not
necessary to require a larger upfront
payment from it in Auction 97. The
Commission determined that waiver
under such circumstances served the
public interest by encouraging prompt
resolution of debts associated with legal
or arbitration proceedings. The
Commission declined, however, to
waive the larger upfront payment
requirement for debts that are subject to
a ‘‘good faith dispute’’ because it
reasoned that such a provision, even for
cured debts, would be too ambiguous to
be efficiently applied during the auction
short-form application process. The
Commission proposes to modify the
former defaulter rule generally to
exclude a default or delinquency that
was the subject of a legal or arbitration
proceeding and was cured upon
resolution of the proceeding. As in the
Auction 97 Former Defaulter Waiver
Order, the Commission does not intend
to include within the scope of this
exclusion any proceedings based on
requests for waiver of a rule requiring
payment of a debt or delinquency. The
Commission seeks comment on whether
its proposed exclusion addresses
parties’ concerns that debts such as
these are not indicative of an applicant’s
financial credibility such that they
should require an applicant to submit a
larger upfront payment. Should the
Commission also exclude debts cured
after resolution of a ‘‘good faith
dispute,’’ and if so, how could such
‘‘good faith disputes’’ be verified during
the short-form application process, if
necessary? Is the proposed general
exclusion for debts cured upon
resolution of a legal or arbitration
proceeding necessary? In the alternative,
should the Commission expect
financially reliable applicants to pay
outstanding defaults on Commission
licenses, or delinquencies on any non-
E:\FR\FM\14NOP1.SGM
14NOP1
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with PROPOSALS
Federal Register / Vol. 79, No. 220 / Friday, November 14, 2014 / Proposed Rules
tax debt owed to any federal agency,
while legal or arbitration proceedings
are pending, even if the applicant’s
liability or the amount of the debt is in
dispute?
96. In their petition, DIRECTV/
EchoStar also maintain that the former
defaulter rule should apply only to
auction participants and those
individuals or entities that are in a
position to affect whether such
applicants meet their auction-related
financial responsibilities and urge the
exclusion of debts/delinquencies
relating to personal obligations of
officers or directors of entities that are
not the auction applicant, e.g.,
excluding personal obligations of
officers and directors of the applicant’s
parent companies. More recent requests
to amend the former defaulter rule do
not include any suggestion to limit the
scope of individuals and entities that an
applicant needs to consider in
evaluating its former defaulter status.
97. In implementing the former
defaulter provisions, the Commission
has included the applicant’s affiliates,
its controlling interests, and affiliates of
its controlling interests in determining if
an applicant is a former defaulter. The
Commission recognizes, however, that
some of the individuals and entities that
fall within these definitions may play
no role in the applicant’s general
financial responsibilities and may not
affect an applicant’s ability to meet its
financial obligations arising from an
auction. Therefore, the Commission
seeks comment on possible ways to
amend the former defaulter provisions
to apply only to individuals and entities
that play a role in the applicant’s
financial responsibilities. If the
Commission were to adopt DIRECTV/
EchoStar’s proposal to include only
individuals or entities that are in a
position to affect whether such
applicants meet their auction-related
financial responsibilities, how could it
verify who would fit within such a
category? In their request for waiver,
DIRECTV/EchoStar suggest specifically
not applying the rule to officers and
directors of parent entities. Under such
an option, however, what would
prevent applicants from evading the
rule by simply creating a shell company
to be the auction applicant?
98. Another option would be to limit
the former defaulter inquiry to those
individuals or entities that an applicant
must disclose on its short-form
application pursuant to 47 CFR 1.2112.
For non-DEs, this would limit the
inquiry to the applicant and disclosable
interest holders under 47 CFR 1.2112(a).
For DEs, the Commission could, under
this option, continue to include those
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:06 Nov 13, 2014
Jkt 235001
individuals and entities that are
attributable to the applicant under 47
CFR 1.2112(b)(iv) in any consideration
of an applicant’s form defaulter status.
As such, the Commission recognizes
that, while such an option may exclude
some individuals and entities not
directly related to an applicant’s auction
finances, it could also expand the scope
of individuals or entities that must be
considered in some respects. The
Commission could limit the inquiry to,
for example, the real party or parties in
interest in the applicant or application,
which must be disclosed pursuant to 47
CFR 1.2112(a)(1). Would this option
capture the individuals and entities that
are in a position to affect whether an
applicant meets its auction-related
financial responsibilities? Would
excluding officers and directors not
otherwise covered by 47
CFR1.2112(a)(1) be inconsistent with
the Commission’s policy to attribute
them for purposes of evaluating
eligibility for designated entity bidding
credits in light of their potential ability
to influence the management or
operation of the applicant?
99. Finally, the Commission seeks
comment as to other possible ways to
limit the scope of the former defaulter
rule. For example, the Commission
could define the rules to include only
defaults or delinquencies related to its
auction payments, or defaults or
delinquencies on debt owed only to the
Commission as opposed to those owed
on other government non-tax debt, such
as student loans. The Commission
notes, however, that such further
limitations may not be necessary given
the other limitations that it proposes.
B. Commonly Controlled Entities
100. The Commission proposes to
codify an established competitive
bidding procedure that prohibits the
same individual or entity from filing
more than one short-form application.
Additionally, the Commission proposes
a new rule that would prevent entities
that are exclusively controlled by a
single individual or set of individuals
from qualifying to bid on licenses in the
same or overlapping geographic areas in
a specific auction on more than one
short-form application.
101. Background. The Commission’s
competitive bidding procedures have
long prohibited the same individual or
entity from submitting multiple shortform applications in any auction. This
restriction prevents duplicative filings
and may avert anticompetitive bidding
behavior.
102. There is currently no similar
procedure for commonly controlled
entities. The competitive bidding rules
PO 00000
Frm 00053
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
68189
and procedures currently contain no
explicit prohibition on commonly
controlled entities participating in the
same auction and bidding on the same
licenses. Several years ago, the
Commission declined to set aside the
results of an auction based on
allegations relating to the participation
of separate applicants that were
commonly controlled. In that decision,
the Commission acknowledged that
auction participation by commonly
controlled applicants could serve
legitimate business purposes if such
entities have different business plans,
financing requirements, or marketing
needs; however, it noted that there
could be risks inherent in allowing
commonly controlled bidders to
participate in an auction. See Petition
for Reconsideration and Motion for Stay
of Paging Systems, Inc., Memorandum
Opinion and Order, 25 FCC Rcd 4036
(2010).
103. Discussion. The Commission
proposes to amend its competitive
bidding rules to codify its restriction on
the filing of multiple auction
applications by the same individual or
entity and to adopt a new rule that
would prevent entities that are
controlled exclusively by the same
single individual or set of individuals
from qualifying to bid based on multiple
auction applications for the same or
overlapping geographic license areas. By
proposing these amendments to its Part
1 competitive bidding rules, the
Commission seeks to improve the
transparency and efficiency of the
auction process, by making clearer who
the qualified bidders actually are and
ensuring against the potential for
anticompetitive auction behavior.
104. Duplicate auction applications.
The Commission proposes to amend 47
CFR 1.2105 to prohibit the same
individual or entity from filing more
than one short-form application for an
auction. The Commission observes that
in contexts other than competitive
bidding, its rules already limit
repetitious or conflicting applications.
Prohibiting the same individual or
entity from filing multiple applications
to participate in an auction protects the
Commission against the burden of
duplicative, repetitious or conflicting
applications. Moreover, in this context,
such applications raise potential
concerns that duplicate filers may be
able to manipulate the auction
process—using, for example, identical
bids or multiple activity waivers—to
pursue potentially anticompetitive ends.
The Commission seeks comment on this
proposal. Are there any specific reasons
the Commission should allow for the
filing of more than a single short-form
E:\FR\FM\14NOP1.SGM
14NOP1
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with PROPOSALS
68190
Federal Register / Vol. 79, No. 220 / Friday, November 14, 2014 / Proposed Rules
application from the same individual or
entity? Commenters should describe any
public interest benefits to support their
positions.
105. Applications by entities
exclusively controlled by the same
individual or set of individuals. The
Commission also proposes to adopt a
new rule to provide that where entities
are under the common, exclusive
control of a single individual or set of
individuals (i.e., a single individual or
same set of individuals is the exclusive
controlling interest of more than one
entity) only one short-form application
from such entities could become
qualified to participate with respect to
any particular geographic license area or
overlapping areas. In defining the
entities that would be subject to this
rule, the Commission proposes to use
the concepts of ‘‘control’’ or
‘‘controlling interest’’ from 47 CFR
1.2110, which also applies by its terms
to DEs. Even when applicants are not
identical, if more than one applicant is
under the exclusive control of a single
individual or set of individuals, such
common control may allow the
controlling individual or set of
individuals to attempt to gain
advantages in the bidding process based
on certain coordinated bidding actions
(e.g., tied bids, activity waivers). While
such entities may have different
business plans, financing, accounting,
non-controlling interest holders or
minority investors, if they are under
exclusive control of a single individual
or set of individuals, under the
Commission’s proposal those entities
could not become qualified to bid in an
auction with respect to the same or
overlapping geographic license areas.
The Commission seeks comment on this
proposal and on specific alternatives to
address its concerns.
106. Multiple applicants under the
common control of a single individual
or set of individuals may coordinate
their bidding actions in ways not
available to a single bidder, and may, in
some cases, derive some advantage from
doing so. For example, such multiple
applicants would have more activity
waivers to use to ensure that the auction
remains open, or would be able to
submit identical bids on a license in
ways intended to exploit auction
bidding procedures. In addition, such
multiple applicants could potentially
coordinate their bidding to gain some
advantage in the context of random tiebreakers or through increasing the
bidding activity on a single license in
order to raise minimum acceptable bids
more quickly through application of the
exponential smoothing formula.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:06 Nov 13, 2014
Jkt 235001
107. Further, the mere presence of
commonly controlled applicants making
identical bids in a single auction may
damage the transparency of the auction
process. For example, the placing of
multiple identical bids by commonly
controlled applicants may mislead other
bidders about the extent of bidding
competition, especially in an
anonymous bidding auction where
competitors are unable to discern
whether bids are placed by commonly
controlled applicants or independent
competitors. The Commission
anticipates that these and other
potentially problematic behaviors could
be curbed by requiring such applicants
to participate as a single applicant with
respect to any particular geographic
license area or overlapping areas.
108. Do commenters share the
Commission’s concern that the
participation of commonly controlled
applicants in an auction potentially
undermines evenhandedness and
transparency in the auction process?
Commenters opposing the
Commission’s proposals should indicate
how codifying its existing auction
procedure and/or adopting its new
proposed rule would harm the
efficiency or undermine the
competitiveness of the Commission’s
current auction process. The
Commission notes that to the extent that
the commonly controlled entities have
an interest in holding licenses won at
auction separately, such entities might
consider assigning the licenses to
related entities in the secondary market.
Are there legitimate business reasons for
filing these types of applications that
the Commission has failed to consider
that could be undermined by its
proposal?
C. Joint Bidding
109. The Commission initiates a
review of its rules and policies
governing joint bidding and other
arrangements in order to ensure that
they fulfill its statutory objectives, given
the changes in the mobile wireless
marketplace since the Commission’s
initial adoption of its bidding rules two
decades ago, and the increasing
importance of spectrum for service
providers to meet consumer demand for
mobile wireless services. The
Commission’s goal in reviewing these
rules and policies is to ensure that they
preserve and promote competition in
the mobile wireless marketplace and
facilitate competition among bidders at
auction, while providing potential
bidders with greater clarity regarding
the types of joint bidding arrangements
that would be permissible.
PO 00000
Frm 00054
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
110. Consistent with the
Commission’s commitment in the
Mobile Spectrum Holdings Report and
Order, it seeks to develop a record on
how joint bidding and other
arrangements affect competition in the
mobile wireless marketplace, and the
appropriate policies and procedures for
substantive competitive review of joint
bidding. Policies Regarding Mobile
Spectrum Holdings; Expanding the
Economic and Innovation Opportunities
of Spectrum Through Incentive
Auctions, 79 FR 39977, Jul. 11, 2014
(Mobile Spectrum Holdings Report and
Order). In that regard, the Commission
notes that the scope of its inquiry here—
unlike its other proposals in the NPRM
applies only to joint bidding and other
arrangements in auctions of licenses
likely to be used for mobile telephony/
mobile broadband services.
111. To best serve the public interest
and preserve and promote robust
competition, the Commission also
proposes to adopt policies tailored to
the characteristics of joint bidding and
other arrangements and the likely
competitive effects on the mobile
wireless marketplace. Specifically, the
Commission tentatively concludes that
it would best serve the public interest to
retain the current rules governing joint
bidding arrangements among nonnationwide providers and to prohibit
joint bidding arrangements among
nationwide providers. In addition, the
Commission seeks comment on whether
it should revise any of its current rules
as applied to arrangements between
nationwide providers and other entities,
including its rules governing short-form
applications. Further, the Commission
seeks comment on whether any
revisions to its rules governing longform applications are necessary in light
of its consideration of the potential
harms and benefits of joint bidding and
other arrangements.
112. Background. Rules and Policies
Governing Joint Bidding. In 1994, the
Commission adopted rules to serve the
objectives of the Act by preventing
parties, especially the largest firms, from
agreeing in advance to bidding strategies
that divide the market according to their
strategic interests and disadvantage
other bidders. See Implementation of
Section 309(j) of the Communications
Act—Competitive Bidding, 59 FR 22980,
May 4, 1994 (Competitive Bidding
Second Report and Order). The
Commission also sought to help ensure
that the government receives a fair
market price for the use of the spectrum.
In the Competitive Bidding Second
Report and Order, the Commission
further concluded that adopting
safeguards to prevent collusive behavior
E:\FR\FM\14NOP1.SGM
14NOP1
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with PROPOSALS
Federal Register / Vol. 79, No. 220 / Friday, November 14, 2014 / Proposed Rules
among bidders would help ensure
prompt delivery of services (including
to rural areas), rapid deployment of new
services and technologies, development
of competitive markets, and wide access
to a variety of services. Moreover, the
Commission observed that collusive
conduct among bidders could prevent
the formation of a competitive postauction market structure. At the same
time, the Commission recognized that if
anticollusion rules are too strict or are
not sufficiently clear, they could
prevent the formation of efficiency
enhancing bidding consortia that pool
capital and expertise and reduce entry
barriers for small firms and other
entities that might not otherwise be able
to compete in the auction process.
113. The Commission concluded that,
in most cases, the number of bidders
likely to participate in the auction,
auction design safeguards, and existing
antitrust law would effectively deter
collusion. However, the Commission
also adopted certain measures to help
ensure collusion would not jeopardize
the competitiveness of the auction
process. Importantly, the Commission
found these safeguards sufficient in the
context of other competition-related
determinations it had made regarding
the initial licensing of Broadband PCS
licenses through competitive bidding.
Specifically, the Commission had set a
limit on the amount of broadband PCS
spectrum that the incumbent cellular
licensees in each market could acquire
at the upcoming PCS auctions as well as
a separate limit on the amount of such
spectrum that any bidder could acquire
at the upcoming Broadband PCS
auctions. In 1991, the Commission had
adopted a cellular cross-interest rule
that substantially limited any affiliation
between the two cellular licensees in an
area.
114. With relatively minor changes
adopted since 1994, the Commission’s
current rules allow potential
participants in a Commission auction,
prior to the short-form application
deadline, to enter into various kinds of
agreements related to the licenses being
auctioned as long as the applicants
disclose on the short-form application
on both the existence (but not the terms
and conditions) of any joint bidding
arrangements and the real-parties-ininterest to the application. After the
short-form application deadline,
applicants may not enter into any
additional arrangements regarding the
amount of bids, bidding strategies or
particular licenses on which they will or
will not bid, subject to certain limited
exceptions, and may not communicate
bidding information to other applicants
for licenses in any of the same
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:06 Nov 13, 2014
Jkt 235001
geographic areas unless those other
applicant(s) were identified on the
short-form application. Post-auction,
winning bidders must disclose on the
long-form application the specific terms,
conditions, and parties involved in any
agreement into which the applicant has
entered, and the winning bidder must
be the same entity that files the longform application.
115. The Commission notes that it has
always made clear with respect to its
rules and policies governing joint
bidding that conduct that is permissible
under the Commission’s Rules may be
prohibited by the antitrust laws, review
under which is subject to other and
differing standards under the Sherman
and Clayton Acts. Specifically, joint
bidding arrangements under section 1 of
the Sherman Act are prohibited if they
constitute a ‘‘contract, combination
. . ., or conspiracy, in restraint of
trade,’’ whereas joint bidding
arrangements subject to section 7 of the
Clayton Act are prohibited if their effect
‘‘may be substantially to lessen
competition, or to tend to create a
monopoly.’’ The Commission’s auction
procedures public notices for specific
auctions caution that compliance with
the disclosure requirements of 47 CFR
1.2105(c) will not insulate a party from
enforcement of the antitrust laws.
Bidders who are found to have violated
the antitrust laws or the Commission’s
rules in connection with their
participation in the competitive bidding
process may be subject to forfeiture,
prohibition from auction participation,
and other sanctions.
116. Evolution of the Mobile Wireless
Marketplace. The Commission adopted
these joint bidding rules 20 years ago
when the mobile wireless industry was
at a nascent stage: For example, at the
end of 1994, the nationwide penetration
rate for mobile wireless service was
approximately 9 percent, compared to
106 percent at the end of 2011.
Moreover, when the Commission
adopted its joint bidding rules in 1994,
it had yet to hold even the first of the
numerous auctions it has conducted in
its history of licenses likely to be used
for mobile telephony/mobile broadband
services.
117. The Commission’s competitive
bidding rules, as adopted in 1994,
reflected the developing nature of the
mobile wireless industry, as the
Commission sought to promote
economic growth in the ‘‘new wireless
services’’ and to enhance access to
telecommunication services by
encouraging broad participation in the
provision of spectrum-based services
and ensuring that spectrum-based
services are available to a wide range of
PO 00000
Frm 00055
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
68191
consumers. In 1998, the Commission
observed again that much of the mobile
telephone market was still in its
infancy.
118. Since 1994, and particularly in
the past decade, the marketplace has
changed significantly. It is no longer
nascent. Consumer demand for wireless
services has exploded, with the industry
focus changing from the provision of
mobile voice services to the provision of
mobile broadband services. The
adoption of smartphones and tablet
computers, and the widespread use of
mobile applications, combined with the
increasing deployment of high-speed 3G
and now 4G technologies, is driving
significantly more intensive use of
mobile networks and increasing
providers’ need for spectrum. In
addition, during the past decade, the
wireless marketplace has undergone
significant consolidation, with a
reduction from six to four nationwide
providers, an increase in the market
share of the major providers, and a
smaller number of regional and local
providers. Indeed, by December 2013,
the top four facilities-based nationwide
providers had combined market share of
approximately 97 percent of subscribers.
See UBS Investment Research, US
Wireless 411: Version 51, Mar. 18, 2014,
Figure 21 at 14.
119. Consistent with the evolution of
the mobile wireless marketplace and the
Commission’s statutory directives and
policy goals, it continues to strive to
adopt policies to preserve and promote
consumer choice and competition
among multiple service providers,
promote the efficient and intensive use
of spectrum, maximize economic
opportunity, and foster the deployment
of innovative technologies. For instance,
the Commission recently concluded in
the Mobile Spectrum Holdings Report
and Order that any mobile spectrum
limit on the initial licensing of a
spectrum band through competitive
bidding should be articulated and
applied prior to the start of the auction
in order to provide bidders greater
certainty regarding how many licenses
they would be permitted to acquire.
120. In the Mobile Spectrum Holdings
Report and Order, the Commission
established a market-based spectrum
reserve for the Incentive Auction of up
to 30 megahertz in each license area,
recognizing that the Incentive Auction
represents a once-in-a-generation
opportunity to auction significant
amounts of greenfield low-band
spectrum. The Commission limited
nationwide providers from bidding on
reserved spectrum in Partial Economic
Areas (PEAs) where they hold 45
megahertz or more of suitable and
E:\FR\FM\14NOP1.SGM
14NOP1
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with PROPOSALS
68192
Federal Register / Vol. 79, No. 220 / Friday, November 14, 2014 / Proposed Rules
available below-1–GHz spectrum. By
contrast, the Commission permitted
regional and local service providers to
bid on reserved spectrum in all PEAs,
observing that non-nationwide service
providers present a significantly lower
risk of effectively denying their rivals
access to low band spectrum to
foreclose competition or to raise rivals’
costs because of their relative lack of
resources. At the same time, in the
Mobile Spectrum Holdings Report and
Order, the Commission placed no
limitation on the amount of spectrum
that bidders could acquire in the AWS–
3 auction.
121. In the Mobile Spectrum Holdings
Report and Order, the Commission also
stated it would consider in a further
notice of proposed rulemaking possible
changes to certain auction rules relating
to joint bidding arrangements and
strategies in the Incentive Auction. The
Commission here undertakes a
reexamination of its auction rules on
these issues, including but not limited
to their application in the Incentive
Auction.
122. Discussion. In light of the
changes in the mobile wireless
marketplace since the Commission
adopted the current joint bidding rules
20 years ago, the Commission reviews
its rules on joint bidding and other
arrangements to ensure that the
potential competitive harms that may
arise out of such arrangements do not
outweigh any public interest benefits.
To best serve the public interest and
preserve and promote robust
competition into the foreseeable future,
the Commission seeks to further its
statutory objectives by adopting policies
tailored to the type of arrangement and
its likely competitive effect on the
conduct of the auction and on the
mobile wireless marketplace.
Specifically, the Commission tentatively
concludes that it would serve the public
interest to retain the current rules
governing joint bidding and other
arrangements among non-nationwide
providers, but to prohibit certain joint
bidding and other arrangements among
nationwide providers. In addition, the
Commission seeks comment on whether
the Commission should revise any of its
current rules as applied to arrangements
between nationwide providers and other
entities, including its rules governing
short-form applications. Further, the
Commission seeks comment on whether
any revisions to its rules governing longform applications are necessary in light
of its consideration of the potential
harms and benefits of joint bidding and
other arrangements.
123. For purposes of this proceeding,
the Commission defines ‘‘joint bidding
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:06 Nov 13, 2014
Jkt 235001
and other arrangements’’ to include any
bidding consortia, joint venture,
partnership, or agreement,
understanding, or other arrangement
entered into relating to the competitive
bidding process, including any
agreement relating to post-auction
market structure or operation. In light of
the Commission’s focus on promoting
and preserving competition, it considers
this definition to include not only
arrangements among entities that apply
to bid in an auction, but also
arrangements between entities that
apply to bid in an auction and those
entities that do not, insofar as such
arrangements have the potential to affect
competition in the mobile wireless
telephony/mobile broadband
marketplace.
124. Competitive Effects of Joint
Bidding and Other Arrangements. When
assessing the competitive effects of joint
bidding and other arrangements, the
Commission must ensure that its
policies and rules facilitate access to
spectrum in a manner that promotes
competition to the benefit of consumers.
As the Commission has found in the
Mobile Spectrum Holdings Report and
Order, in order for there to be robust
competition, multiple competing service
providers must have access to or hold
sufficient spectrum to be able to enter
the marketplace or expand output
rapidly in response to any price
increase, reduction in quality, or other
competitive change that would harm
consumer welfare.
125. Joint conduct or competitor
collaboration that is more limited in
scope and does not result in a full
integration of economic activity does
not end all competition between
participants post bidding and is
analyzed differently from joint ventures
that fully integrate the participants
downstream competition. The latter, in
certain circumstances, may be properly
analyzed as a merger. Either type of
competitor collaboration however may
result in procompetitive benefits and/or
anticompetitive effects.
126. Because some joint bidding and
other competitor collaborations
contemplate competition among
participants post auction, they raise the
risk that the spectrum acquired through
a winning bid will be allocated among
the joint venture participants in a
manner that could harm the public
interest. Because the joint venture may
be comprised of same market
competitors, the arrangement may
require proper safeguards to prevent the
exchange of competitively sensitive
price and output information, ensure
independent decision making or
otherwise avoid lessening competition
PO 00000
Frm 00056
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
among the participants in the
downstream mobile wireless
marketplace.
127. Joint bidding and other
arrangements, however, also have the
potential to result in procompetitive
benefits if they enable participation in
auctions by those otherwise without
sufficient financial resources to bid, or
otherwise reduce entry costs into a
geographic area or enable the joint
bidders to compete more robustly
against other competitors in the
marketplace. For example, the pooling
of capital resources could allow smaller
providers to better exploit financial
economies of scale and enter into
bidding for geographic areas that
otherwise would not have been
accessible, which may be particularly
important given the high capital costs of
network deployment and spectrum
acquisition.
128. The Commission seeks comment
on the foregoing analysis. The
Commission’s public interest review of
applications for assignment of licenses
through competitive bidding generally
encompasses a review of the
competitive effects of such assignments.
In light of the changing marketplace and
consistent with the Commission’s recent
emphasis in the Mobile Spectrum
Holdings proceeding on the need for
clearly-defined rules prior to the auction
on the licenses a bidder would be
permitted to acquire, the Commission
seeks comment on how best to conduct
its competitive review of joint bidding
arrangements going forward.
129. Given the potential benefits and
harms of different types of
arrangements, the Commission seeks
comment on the rules and procedures
that should govern its review of joint
bidding and other arrangements entered
into relating to the competitive bidding
process, including any agreement
relating to post-auction market structure
or operation. In addition, the
Commission seeks comment on whether
the distinctions as to arrangements
among non-nationwide providers,
among nationwide providers, and
between nationwide providers and other
entities—provide an effective
framework for addressing the relative
harms and benefits of joint bidding
arrangements in light of its goal of
providing clearly-defined rules for
potential bidders in auctions. Further,
the Commission seeks comment on
whether these rules or procedures
should differ in instances in which it
has adopted a mobile spectrum holding
limit for the initial licensing of a
particular spectrum band through
competitive bidding and, if so, how the
type of mobile spectrum holding limit
E:\FR\FM\14NOP1.SGM
14NOP1
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with PROPOSALS
Federal Register / Vol. 79, No. 220 / Friday, November 14, 2014 / Proposed Rules
and the statutory goals applicable to the
particular auction should affect these
rules and procedures.
130. For purposes of the joint bidding
rules, the Commission proposes to
define ‘‘nationwide’’ providers to
include the providers in the U.S. with
networks that cover a majority of the
population and land area of the
country—currently, Verizon Wireless,
AT&T, Sprint and T-Mobile—with other
providers being considered ‘‘nonnationwide’’ providers. The
Commission seeks comment on how
this definition of nationwide providers
should take into account entities
partially owned by Verizon Wireless,
AT&T, Sprint and T-Mobile. Should the
definition include entities that are
‘‘affiliates’’ (as that term is defined in its
rules for attributing revenues to small
businesses) of the four providers,
entities with spectrum holdings that
would be attributable to these four
providers (as defined by its mobile
spectrum holdings rules), or a category
of entities defined in some other
manner?
131. Arrangements among NonNationwide Providers. Considering the
current competitive landscape and the
need for access to spectrum by nonnationwide providers, the Commission
tentatively concludes that its current
rules are sufficient to prevent any
potential competitive harm from
outweighing the likely public interest
benefits associated with allowing joint
bidding and other arrangements among
non-nationwide providers. For example,
joint bidding and other arrangements
among non-nationwide providers can
better overcome the challenging capital
costs of license acquisition to maintain
or increase their competitive presence to
the benefit of American consumers. In
light of the relatively small size and
scope of non-nationwide providers
following substantial consolidation
since the Commission’s current rules
were adopted, and the increased costs of
spectrum and other capital expenditures
necessary to provide mobile broadband
service over large license areas, the
Commission believes it is highly
unlikely in most circumstances that
such arrangements would lead to
competitive harm or otherwise harm the
public interest. Moreover, in the Mobile
Spectrum Holdings Report and Order,
the Commission observed that nonnationwide service providers presented
a significantly lower risk of effectively
denying their rivals access to spectrum
in order to foreclose downstream
competition or to raise rivals’ costs
because of their relative lack of
resources. The Commission seeks
comment on these views in connection
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:06 Nov 13, 2014
Jkt 235001
with the competitive impact of joint
bidding and other arrangements.
132. Commenters proposing any
changes to the Commission’s joint
bidding rules for arrangements among
non-nationwide providers should
discuss why such changes are necessary
to address particular competitive
concerns and whether, on balance, such
changes would ensure that the
procompetitive benefits and bidding
flexibility arising out of its current rules
remain in place. In addition, the
Commission seeks comment on whether
any types of arrangements between nonnationwide service providers and
potential new entrants would warrant
closer examination of the competitive
effects and, if so, whether any changes
to its joint bidding rules are necessary
to address any such scenarios.
133. Arrangements among
Nationwide Providers. In contrast, the
Commission tentatively concludes that
joint bidding arrangements between or
among nationwide providers likely
would raise competitive concerns, as
these arrangements would have the
potential to serve as a vehicle for
anticompetitive conduct by altering post
auction incentives to compete, and thus,
would outweigh any public interest
benefits from such arrangements such as
the attainment of scale or scope
economies. As the Commission noted in
the Mobile Spectrum Holdings Report
and Order, the mobile wireless
marketplace today is characterized by
factors—such as high market
concentration, high margins and high
barriers to entry—that increase the
potential for anticompetitive conduct. In
particular, by year end 2013, the top
four facilities-based nationwide
providers had a combined market share,
as measured by the number of
subscribers or mobile wireless service
revenues, of at least 97 percent.
134. Moreover, in light of these
factors, joint bidding arrangements
among nationwide providers would
reduce the participants’ ability or
incentive to compete independently,
which would lessen competition in the
downstream mobile wireless
marketplace and could harm American
consumers by increasing the price or
reducing the quality of mobile wireless
services. Because of these greater risks
of public interest harms, the
Commission believes it is unlikely that
the potential benefits of joint bidding
arrangements among nationwide
providers would outweigh these risks.
The Commission seeks comment on this
analysis.
135. Further, as the Commission has
emphasized recently, it is important to
provide bidders with certainty and
PO 00000
Frm 00057
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
68193
clarity in advance of the start of an
auction regarding whether any
limitations on their ability to acquire
licenses would apply. In that regard, the
Commission observes that post-auction
enforcement of antitrust law—
envisioned as a safeguard by the
Commission in 1994—may not be as
well suited to preventing anticompetitive joint bidding arrangements
as the bright-line prohibition the
Commission proposes herein. In
addition, the Commission notes that,
while in 1994 bright-line prohibitions
on certain types of bidding
arrangements might not have been
ideally suited for an industry at a
nascent stage, the mobile wireless
industry today is much more mature
than it was in 1994. Moreover, the limit
set by the Commission at that time on
the amount of broadband PCS spectrum
that the two incumbent cellular
licensees in each market could acquire
at the auctions effectively eliminated
the incentives of those providers to
enter into joint bidding arrangements,
which would have raised significant
competitive concerns.
136. Accordingly, the Commission
tentatively concludes that it would best
serve the public interest at this time to
have a bright-line rule that would
prohibit joint bidding and other
arrangements among nationwide
providers, including agreements to
participate in an auction through a
newly formed joint entity, given that
such arrangements have a greater
potential to harm the public interest by
negatively affecting the competitive
bidding process and downstream
competition in the provision of mobile
wireless services. The Commission
seeks comment on the costs and benefits
of prohibiting applications to participate
in an auction that involve joint bidding
and other arrangements, such as a new
joint venture, between two or more
nationwide providers. The Commission
notes that its tentative conclusion to
prohibit joint bidding and other
arrangements between two nationwide
providers would also include
prohibiting arrangements among two
nationwide providers, together with
other entities.
137. Arrangements between a
Nationwide Provider and Other Entities.
The Commission seeks comment on
what policies and procedures should
apply to bidding arrangements between
a single nationwide provider and other
entities, either non-nationwide
providers or potential new entrants, in
order to promote competition. Under
what circumstances would these
arrangements raise competitive
concerns? Under what circumstances
E:\FR\FM\14NOP1.SGM
14NOP1
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with PROPOSALS
68194
Federal Register / Vol. 79, No. 220 / Friday, November 14, 2014 / Proposed Rules
would these arrangements likely result
in public interest benefits, such as the
expansion of mobile wireless services in
additional geographic areas and
increasing access to capital by more
applicants to acquire spectrum? Should
any limits apply to these types of
arrangements, or should the
Commission continue to review these
types of arrangements on a case-by-case
basis?
138. If the Commission reviews these
types of arrangements on a case-by-case
basis, what process and factors should
it use in assessing the competitive
implications? The Commission’s current
approach for reviewing joint ventures in
the context of assignment or transfer of
licenses involves the determination of
the appropriate market definitions and
the likelihood of public interest harm
from the incentive and ability of the
joint venture to act anticompetitively,
either unilaterally or in concert with
other service providers. Should a
similar approach apply to its
competitive review of joint bidding
arrangements? How should a case-bycase approach to review joint bidding
arrangements be designed to provide
clarity to potential bidders? What are
the costs and benefits of Commission
review of joint bidding arrangements on
a case-by-case basis, including the
administrative cost and burden to make
such a case-by-case determination prior
to the start of an auction?
139. To make case-by-case
determinations regarding arrangements
between nationwide providers and other
entities, should the Commission modify
any of its current rules that apply to the
pre-auction review process? In
particular, should the terms and
conditions of such joint bidding
arrangements be disclosed prior to the
auction, in the short-form application,
or even prior to the filing of that
application? If so, are there changes to
its rules or procedures that would be
necessary to protect any confidential
information? If the deadline for
disclosure of terms and conditions is in
advance of the short-form application
deadline, how would this process be
affected by the rules prohibiting certain
types of communications? Commenters
on this issue should include any costs
or benefits to changing the rules and
procedures regarding the disclosure of a
joint bidding requirement.
140. If the Commission were to make
a determination that the potential harms
associated with a particular joint
bidding arrangement outweigh the
potential benefits, what remedies
should it impose either at the short-form
application stage or the long-form
application stage? For example, should
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:06 Nov 13, 2014
Jkt 235001
the Commission find that a short-form
application is unacceptable or
incomplete and bar the applicant from
bidding in the auction? Should it find
that an applicant at the long-form stage
is unqualified to hold the license and
deemed in default? Commenters
proposing particular remedies should
discuss the costs and benefits of such
remedies.
141. Other Issues. The Commission’s
current rules require the entity that filed
the short-form application to be the
same entity that files the long-form
application seeking consent to acquire a
new license. The Commission’s public
interest review of long-form
applications generally encompasses a
review of the competitive effects of such
assignments, as would its review of a
secondary market transaction to
disseminate licenses from a joint entity
to its individual members. The
Commission seeks comment on whether
it is necessary to modify its current joint
bidding rules, standards, and
procedures that apply to the postauction review of long-form
applications or review of a secondary
market transaction to disseminate
licenses from a joint entity to its
individual members, in order to
promote competition in the mobile
wireless marketplace.
142. Further, the Commission
proposes to clarify a provision under 47
CFR 1.2107(g) which permits DEs to
participate in an auction as a nonlegally-recognizable consortium, with a
requirement that each member of the
consortium file separate applications for
licenses covered by the winning bids of
the consortium. This provision is
applicable only in the DE context,
where there are special provisions
regarding the attribution of revenues for
purposes of qualifying for bidding
credits. The Commission seeks
comment on this clarification.
D. Miscellaneous Part 1 Revisions
143. Background. Part 1, Subpart Q, of
the Commission’s rules generally
governs competitive bidding
proceedings to assign spectrum licenses.
The Commission proposes changes to
two of its part 1, Subpart Q, rules, 47
CFR 1.2111 and 1.2112. The
Commission also intends, when it
resolves the issues raised in the
Competitive Bidding NPRM, to resolve
long standing petitions for
reconsideration to its part 1 competitive
bidding rules.
144. Discussion. 47 CFR 1.2111. The
Commission proposes to repeal the first
two paragraphs of 47 CFR 1.2111. It
proposes to repeal 47 CFR 1.2111(a),
under which applicants for assignments
or transfers during the first three years
of a license term must provide the
Commission with detailed contract and
marketing information. The Commission
believes that this requirement places a
burden on licensees without a
corresponding benefit to the
Commission or the public. The
Commission also proposes to repeal 47
CFR 1.2111(b), a never-used unjust
enrichment payment requirement for
broadband PCS C and F block set-aside
licenses.
145. 47 CFR 1.2112. The
Commission’s proposed changes to this
rule would clarify the auction
application requirements for reporting
an entity’s percentage ownership in the
applicant and in FCC-regulated entities.
The Commission proposes further
changes to specify application
requirements for bidding consortia.
Finally, the Commission proposes to
correct two errors in the rule caused by
the inadvertent substitution of an
incorrect paragraph in the Code of
Federal Regulations publication of the
rule for the correct one published in the
Federal Register summary of the DE
Second Report and Order. Compare 71
FR 26245, 26253, May 4, 2006, with 47
CFR 1.2112, Oct. 1, 2006. The first error
was the addition of a requirement that
DE short-form applicants list and
summarize all their agreements that
support their DE eligibility, a
requirement that the Commission
intended to apply only to long-form
applicants. The Commission proposes to
delete the requirement with respect to
the short form. The second error was the
deletion of a requirement that DE shortform applicants list the parties with
which they have lease or resale
arrangements for any of the DE
applicants’ spectrum licenses. The
Commission proposes to reinstate this
requirement.
146. The Commission seeks comment
on these proposals.
E. Initial Regulatory Flexibility Analysis
147. As required by the Regulatory
Flexibility Act of 1980, as amended
(RFA), the Commission has prepared
this Initial Regulatory Flexibility
Analysis (IRFA) concerning the possible
significant economic impact on small
entities by the policies and rules
proposed in the Competitive Bidding
NPRM. Written public comments are
requested for this IRFA. Comments to
the IRFA must be identified as
responses to the IRFA and filed by the
deadlines for comments on the
Competitive Bidding NPRM in the Dates
section. The Commission will send a
copy of the Competitive Bidding NPRM,
including the IRFA, to the Chief
PO 00000
Frm 00058
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
E:\FR\FM\14NOP1.SGM
14NOP1
Federal Register / Vol. 79, No. 220 / Friday, November 14, 2014 / Proposed Rules
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with PROPOSALS
Counsel for Advocacy of the Small
Business Administration.
1. Need for, and Objectives of, the
Proposed Rules
148. The NPRM proposes to: (1)
Provide small businesses greater
opportunity to participate in the
provision of a wide range of spectrumbased services by modifying the
Commission’s eligibility requirements,
updating the standardized schedule of
small business sizes, and eliminating
duplicative reporting requirements,
while also seeking comment on
strengthening the Commission’s rules to
prevent the unjust enrichment of
ineligible entities; (2) Amend the
Commission’s former defaulter rule to
balance concerns that the current rule is
overly broad with the Commission’s
continued need to ensure that auction
bidders are financially reliable; (3)
Codify an established competitive
bidding procedure that prohibits the
same individual or entity from
becoming qualified to bid on the basis
of more than one short-form application
in a specific auction; (4) Prevent entities
that are exclusively controlled by a
single individual or set of individuals
from becoming qualified to bid on
overlapping licenses based on more
than one short-form application in a
specific auction; and, (5) Retain the
current rules governing joint bidding
arrangements among non-nationwide
providers and prohibit joint bidding
arrangements among nationwide
providers. The NPRM also provides
notice of the Commission’s intention to
resolve long standing petitions for
reconsideration and proposes necessary
clean-up revisions to the Commission’s
part 1 competitive bidding rules.
149. With respect to small businesses,
the Commission’s proposals seek to
update its rules to reflect that small
businesses need greater opportunities to
gain access to capital so that they may
have an opportunity to participate in the
provision of spectrum-based services in
today’s communications marketplace. In
the past decade, the rapid adoption of
smartphones and tablet computers and
the widespread use of mobile
applications, combined with the
increasing deployment of high-speed 3G
and now 4G technologies, have driven
significantly more intensive use of
mobile networks. This progression from
the provision of mobile voice services to
the provision of mobile broadband
services has increased the need for
access to spectrum. In addition, in the
past decade, the number of small and
regional mobile wireless service
providers has significantly decreased,
yet regional and local service providers
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:06 Nov 13, 2014
Jkt 235001
continue to offer consumers additional
choices in the areas they serve. The
Commission anticipates that by revising
its rules to allow small businesses to
take advantage of the same
opportunities to utilize their spectrum
capacity and gain access to capital as
those afforded to larger licensees, the
Commission can better achieve its
statutory directives. Nonetheless, the
Commission remains mindful of its
obligation to prevent unjust enrichment
of ineligible entities.
2. Description and Estimate of the
Number of Small Entities To Which the
Proposed Rules Will Apply
150. The RFA directs the Commission
to provide a description of and, where
feasible, an estimate of the number of
small entities that will be affected by the
proposed rules, if adopted. The RFA
generally defines the term ‘‘small
entity’’ as having the same meaning as
the terms ‘‘small business,’’ ‘‘small
organization,’’ and ‘‘small government
jurisdiction.’’ In addition, the term
‘‘small business’’ has the same meaning
as the term ‘‘small business concern’’
under the Small Business Act. A small
business concern is one which: (1) Is
independently owned and operated; (2)
is not dominant in its field of operation;
and (3) satisfies any additional criteria
established by the SBA.
151. Small Businesses, Small
Organizations, and Small Governmental
Jurisdictions. If adopted, the NPRM’s
proposals may, over time, affect small
entities that are not easily categorized at
present. The Commission therefore
describes three comprehensive,
statutory small entity size standards
under 5 U.S.C. 601(4). First, nationwide,
there are a total of approximately 27.5
million small businesses, according to
the SBA. In addition, a ‘‘small
organization’’ is generally ‘‘any not-forprofit enterprise which is independently
owned and operated and is not
dominant in its field.’’ Nationwide, as of
2007, there were approximately
1,621,315 small organizations. Finally,
the term ‘‘small governmental
jurisdiction’’ is defined generally as
‘‘governments of cities, towns,
townships, villages, school districts, or
special districts, with a population of
less than fifty thousand.’’ U.S. Census
Bureau (hereinafter, Census Bureau or
Census) data for 2011 indicate that there
were 89,476 local governmental
jurisdictions in the United States. The
Commission estimates that, of this total,
as many as 88,506 entities may qualify
as ‘‘small governmental jurisdictions.’’
Thus, the Commission estimates that
most governmental jurisdictions are
small.
PO 00000
Frm 00059
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
68195
152. Licenses Assigned by Auction.
The changes and additions to the
Commission’s rules proposed in the
NPRM are of general applicability to all
auctionable services. Accordingly, the
IRFA provides a general analysis of the
impact of the proposals on small
businesses rather than a service-byservice analysis. The number of entities
that may apply to participate in future
Commission spectrum auctions is
unknown. Moreover, the number of
small businesses that have participated
in prior spectrum auctions has varied.
As a general matter, the number of
winning bidders that qualify as small
businesses at the close of an auction
does not necessarily represent the
number of small businesses currently in
service. Also, the Commission does not
generally track subsequent business size
unless, in the context of changes in
control, changes in material
relationships or assignments or
transfers, unjust enrichment issues are
implicated.
153. Wireless Telecommunications
Carriers (except satellite). The Census
Bureau defines this category to include
establishments engaged in operating and
maintaining switching and transmission
facilities to provide communications via
the airwaves. Establishments in this
industry have spectrum licenses and
provide services using that spectrum,
such as cellular phone services, paging
services, wireless Internet access, and
wireless video services. The SBA has
developed a small business size
standard for Wireless
Telecommunications Carriers (except
satellite). Under the SBA’s standard, a
business is small if it has 1,500 or fewer
employees. For this category, Census
data for 2007 show that there were 1,383
firms that operated for the entire year.
Of this total, 1,368 firms (approximately
99%) had employment of 999 or fewer
employees and only 15 (approximately
1%) had employment of 1,000
employees or more. Thus under this
category and the associated small
business size standard, the Commission
estimates that the majority of wireless
telecommunications carriers (except
satellite) are small entities that may be
affected by the NPRM’s proposed
actions.
154. Broadband Radio Service and
Educational Broadband Service.
Broadband Radio Service systems,
previously referred to as Multipoint
Distribution Service (MDS) and
Multichannel Multipoint Distribution
Service (MMDS) systems, and ‘‘wireless
cable,’’ transmit video programming to
subscribers and provide two-way high
speed data operations using the
microwave frequencies of the
E:\FR\FM\14NOP1.SGM
14NOP1
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with PROPOSALS
68196
Federal Register / Vol. 79, No. 220 / Friday, November 14, 2014 / Proposed Rules
Broadband Radio Service (BRS) and
Educational Broadband Service (EBS)
(previously referred to as the
Instructional Television Fixed Service
(ITFS)). In connection with the 1996
BRS auction, the Commission
established a small business size
standard as an entity that had annual
average gross revenues of no more than
$40 million in the previous three
calendar years. The BRS auction
resulted in 67 successful bidders
obtaining licensing opportunities for
493 Basic Trading Areas (BTAs). Of the
67 auction winners, 61 met the
definition of a small business. BRS also
includes licensees of stations authorized
prior to the auction. At this time, based
on the Commission’s review of licensing
records, it estimates that of the 61 small
business BRS auction winners, 48
remain small business licensees. In
addition to the 48 small businesses that
hold BTA authorizations, there are
approximately 86 incumbent BRS
licensees that are considered small
entities (18 incumbent BRS licensees do
not meet the small business size
standard). After adding the number of
small business auction licensees to the
number of incumbent licensees not
already counted, there are currently
approximately 133 BRS licensees that
are defined as small businesses under
either the SBA or the Commission’s
rules. In 2009, the Commission
conducted Auction 86, the sale of 78
licenses in the BRS areas. The
Commission established three small
business size standards that were used
in Auction 86: (i) An entity with
attributed average annual gross revenues
that exceeded $15 million and do not
exceed $40 million for the preceding
three years was considered a small
business; (ii) an entity with attributed
average annual gross revenues that
exceeded $3 million and did not exceed
$15 million for the preceding three
years was considered a very small
business; and (iii) an entity with
attributed average annual gross revenues
that did not exceed $3 million for the
preceding three years was considered an
entrepreneur. Auction 86 concluded in
2009 with the sale of 61 licenses. Of the
10 winning bidders, two bidders that
claimed small business status won four
licenses; one bidder that claimed very
small business status won three
licenses; and two bidders that claimed
entrepreneur status won six licenses.
The Commission notes that, as a general
matter, the number of winning bidders
that qualify as small businesses at the
close of an auction does not necessarily
represent the number of small
businesses currently in service.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:06 Nov 13, 2014
Jkt 235001
155. In addition, the SBA’s placement
of Cable Television Distribution
Services in the category of Wired
Telecommunications Carriers is
applicable to cable-based educational
broadcasting services. Since 2007, the
Census Bureau has defined Wired
Telecommunications Carriers as
follows: ‘‘This industry comprises [of]
establishments primarily engaged in
operating and/or providing access to
transmission facilities and infrastructure
that they own and/or lease for the
transmission of voice, data, text, sound,
and video using wired
telecommunications networks.
Transmission facilities may be based on
a single technology or a combination of
technologies.’’ Establishments in this
industry use the wired
telecommunications network facilities
that they operate to provide a variety of
services, such as wired telephony
services, including VoIP services; wired
(cable) audio and video programming
distribution; and wired broadband
Internet services. By exception,
establishments providing satellite
television distribution services using
facilities and infrastructure that they
operate are included in this industry.
The SBA has developed a small
business size standard for this category,
which is: All such firms having 1,500 or
fewer employees. Census data for 2007
shows that there were 3,188 firms that
operated for the duration of that year. Of
those, 3,144 had fewer than 1,000
employees, and 44 firms had more than
1,000 employees. Thus under this
category and the associated small
business size standard, the majority of
such firms can be considered small. In
addition to Census data, the
Commission’s Universal Licensing
System indicates that as of July 2014,
there are 2,006 active EBS licenses. The
Commission estimates that of these
2,006 licenses, the majority are held by
non-profit educational institutions and
school districts, which are by statute
defined as small businesses.
156. Television Broadcasting. As
defined by the Census Bureau, this
category ‘‘comprises [of] establishments
primarily engaged in broadcasting
images together with sound. These
establishments operate television
broadcasting studios and facilities for
the programming and transmission of
programs to the public.’’ The SBA has
created the following small business
size standard for Television
Broadcasting firms: those having $38.5
million or less in annual receipts. The
Commission has estimated the number
of licensed commercial television
stations to be 1,387. In addition,
PO 00000
Frm 00060
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
according to Commission staff review of
the BIA/Kelsey, LLC’s Media Access Pro
Television Database on July 30, 2014,
about 1,276 of an estimated 1,387
commercial television stations (or
approximately 92 percent) had revenues
of $38.5 million or less. The
Commission therefore estimates that the
majority of commercial television
broadcasters are small entities.
157. The Commission notes, however,
that in assessing whether a business
concern qualifies as small, business
(control) affiliations must be included.
The Commission’s estimates, therefore,
likely overstates the number of small
entities that might be affected by the
NPRM’s proposals because the revenue
figure on which it is based does not
include or aggregate revenues from
affiliated companies. In addition, an
element of the definition of ‘‘small
business’’ is that the entity not be
dominant in its field of operation. The
Commission is unable at this time to
define or quantify the criteria that
would establish whether a specific
television station is dominant in its field
of operation. Accordingly, the estimate
of small businesses to which rules may
apply does not exclude any television
station from the definition of a small
business on this basis and is therefore
possibly over-inclusive to that extent.
158. In addition, the Commission has
estimated the number of licensed
noncommercial educational (NCE)
television stations to be 395. These
stations are non-profit, and therefore
considered to be small entities.
159. There are also 2,460 LPTV
stations, including Class A stations, and
3,838 TV translator stations. Given the
nature of these services, the
Commission will presume that all of
these entities qualify as small entities
under the above SBA small business
size standard.
160. Radio Broadcasting. The SBA
defines a radio broadcast station as a
small business if such station has no
more than $38.5 million in annual
receipts. As defined by the Census
Bureau, business concerns in this
industry are those ‘‘primarily engaged in
broadcasting aural programs by radio to
the public.’’ According to review of the
BIA/Kelsey, LLC’s Media Access Pro
Radio Database as of July 30, 2014,
about 11,332 (or about 99.9 percent) of
11,343 commercial radio stations have
revenues of $38.5 million or less and
thus qualify as small entities under the
SBA definition. The Commission notes,
however, that, in assessing whether a
business concern qualifies as small,
business (control) affiliations must be
included. This estimate, therefore, likely
overstates the number of small entities
E:\FR\FM\14NOP1.SGM
14NOP1
Federal Register / Vol. 79, No. 220 / Friday, November 14, 2014 / Proposed Rules
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with PROPOSALS
that might be affected, because the
revenue figure on which it is based does
not include or aggregate revenues from
affiliated companies.
161. In addition, an element of the
definition of ‘‘small business’’ is that the
entity not be dominant in its field of
operation. The Commission is unable at
this time to define or quantify the
criteria that would establish whether a
specific radio station is dominant in its
field of operation. Accordingly, the
estimate of small businesses to which
rules may apply does not exclude any
radio station from the definition of a
small business on this basis and
therefore may be over-inclusive to that
extent. Also, as noted, an additional
element of the definition of ‘‘small
business’’ is that the entity must be
independently owned and operated.
The Commission notes that it is difficult
at times to assess these criteria in the
context of media entities and the
estimates of small businesses to which
they apply may be over-inclusive to this
extent.
3. Description of Projected Reporting,
Recordkeeping, and Other Compliance
Requirements for Small Entities
162. Eligibility for Bidding Credits.
The NPRM proposes changes to the
Commission’s process for evaluating
small business eligibility for bidding
credits. In particular, the NPRM
proposes to repeal the AMR rule and
tentatively concludes that the
Commission should re-examine the
need for the related decade-old policy
that has limited small businesses
seeking bidding credits to providing
primarily retail, facilities-based service
directly to the public with each of their
licenses. Under the AMR, a small
business applicant or licensee must
automatically attribute to itself the gross
revenues of any entity with which it has
an ‘‘attributable material relationship.’’
An applicant or licensee has an AMR
when it has one or more agreements
with any individual entity for the lease
(under either spectrum manager or de
facto transfer leasing arrangements) or
resale (including under a wholesale
arrangement) of, on a cumulative basis,
more than 25 percent of the spectrum
capacity of any individual license held
by the applicant or licensee. The NPRM
seeks comment on the proposal to
repeal the AMR rule, and the
Commission’s tentative conclusions
regarding its need to re-evaluate its
small business policy. Alternatively, the
NPRM also seeks comment on retaining
the Commission’s small business policy
and/or some variation of the AMR rule.
For instance, the NPRM seeks comment
on whether the Commission should
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:06 Nov 13, 2014
Jkt 235001
adopt a rule with some other spectrum
capacity use limit that would render an
applicant ineligible for all current and
future benefits.
163. The NPRM also proposes to
adopt a more flexible approach under
which the Commission would evaluate
small business eligibility on a licenseby-license basis, using a two-pronged
test. The first prong would evaluate
whether an applicant meets the
applicable small business size standard
and is therefore eligible for benefits. To
evaluate small business eligibility, the
NPRM proposes to apply the
Commission’s existing controlling
interest standard and affiliation rules to
determine whether, an entity should be
attributable based on whether that entity
has de jure or de facto control of, or is
affiliated with, the applicant’s overall
business venture. Once the first prong
has been met, the Commission would
evaluate eligibility under the second
prong. Under the second prong, the
NPRM proposes to determine an entity’s
eligibility to retain small business
benefits on a license-by-license basis,
based on whether it has maintained de
jure and de facto control of the license.
Under this proposed license-by-license
approach, an entity will not necessarily
lose its eligibility for all current and
future small business benefits solely
because of a decision associated with
any particular license. Instead, while a
small business might incur unjust
enrichment obligations if it relinquishes
de jure or de facto control of any
particular license for which it claimed
benefits, so long as the revenues of its
attributable interest holders (i.e., the
DE’s affiliates, its controlling interests,
and the affiliates of its controlling
interests) continue to qualify under the
relevant small business size standard, it
could still retain its eligibility to retain
current and future benefits on existing
and future licenses. The NPRM seeks
comment on the proposed two-pronged
approach to evaluate attribution and
establish eligibility for small business
benefits.
164. The NPRM also proposes to
modify the Commission’s secondary
market rules to comport with the
Commission’s proposed approach to
assessing small business eligibility.
Specifically, the NPRM proposes to
modify the language in 47 CFR
1.9020(d)(4) to remove the conflicting
reference to the control standard of 47
CFR 1.2110 in order to make clear that
small business lessors are fully subject
to the same de facto control standard for
spectrum manager leasing that applies
to all other licensees. This modification
should clarify that 47 CFR 1.9010 alone
defines whether a licensee, including a
PO 00000
Frm 00061
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
68197
small business, retains de facto control
of the spectrum that it leases to a
spectrum lessee in the context of
spectrum manager leasing.
165. The NPRM seeks comment on
whether any changes are appropriate to
the Commission’s unjust enrichment
rules that provide additional safeguards
by requiring repayment of small
business benefits where an applicant
loses eligibility for any reason.
Specifically, the NPRM invites comment
on, among other things, whether to
adjust the Commission’s current five
year unjust enrichment schedule either
in terms of the duration of the
requirements or the percentages of the
repayment schedule. The NPRM also
seeks comment on how best the
Commission can continue to scrutinize
applications and proposed transactions
to ensure that only eligible entities
receive benefits, while not undermining
the Act’s directive to ensure that DEs are
given the opportunity to participate in
the provision of spectrum-based
services. Specifically, the NPRM seeks
comment on adopting a 10 year unjust
enrichment repayment schedule similar
to the one it adopted in 2006, but
vacated by the Third Circuit for lack of
notice.
166. Bidding Credits. The NPRM
examines the primary way that the
Commission facilitates participation by
small businesses at auction through its
bidding credit program. Bidding credits
operate as a percentage discount on the
winning bid amounts of a qualifying
small business. By making the
acquisition of spectrum licenses more
affordable for new and existing small
businesses, bidding credits facilitate
their access to needed capital. The
Commission establishes eligibility for
bidding credits for each auctionable
service, adopting one or more
definitions of the small businesses that
will be eligible. The Commission’s small
business definitions have been based on
an applicant’s average annual gross
revenues over a three-year period. The
NPRM proposes to increase the general
schedule of size standards in its part 1
rules, measured by gross revenues, for
purposes of determining an entity’s
eligibility for a bidding preference.
Specifically, the NPRM proposes to
revise the standardized schedule in 47
CFR 1.2110(f) as follows: (1) Businesses
with average annual gross revenues for
the preceding three years not exceeding
$4 million would be eligible for a 35
percent bidding credit; (2) Businesses
with average annual gross revenues for
the preceding three years not exceeding
$20 million would be eligible for a 25
percent bidding credit; and (3)
Businesses with average annual gross
E:\FR\FM\14NOP1.SGM
14NOP1
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with PROPOSALS
68198
Federal Register / Vol. 79, No. 220 / Friday, November 14, 2014 / Proposed Rules
revenues for the preceding three years
not exceeding $55 million would be
eligible for a 15 percent bidding credit.
The NPRM also asks about alternative
methods for setting new gross revenues
thresholds.
167. The NPRM seeks comment on
whether to adopt a small business size
standard based on criteria other than
gross revenues, and proposes to
continue the Commission’s practice of
evaluating which small business
definitions will apply on a service-byservice basis, based upon associated
capital requirements for a particular
service. In addition, the NPRM seeks
comment on whether to increase the
bidding credit percentages (i.e.,
discount amounts) applicable to
associated small business categories.
The NPRM also seeks comment on
whether any revisions the Commission
adopts in this proceeding to its part 1
schedule of small business size
standards and associated bidding credit
percentage levels should apply to the
specific small business definitions and
bidding credit percentages the
Commission previously adopted for
specific services, and, if so, how such
revisions would be implemented. The
NPRM proposes that any new rules
adopted in this proceeding would apply
to the 600 MHz band spectrum licenses
to be offered in the BIA. In the BIA
proceeding, the Commission adopted a
15 percent bidding credit for small
businesses (defined as entities with
average annual gross revenues for the
preceding three years not exceeding $40
million) and a 25 percent bidding credit
for very small businesses (defined as
entities with average annual gross
revenues for the preceding three years
not exceeding $15 million).
Accordingly, the NPRM proposes to
adopt, for the 600 MHz band, increases
in the gross revenues thresholds
associated with the 25 percent and 15
percent bidding credits that are
consistent with the increased gross
revenues thresholds proposed in the
NPRM for the standardized schedule in
the Commission’s part 1 competitive
bidding rules. The NPRM also seeks
comment on whether the Commission
should adopt a third small business
bidding credit tier for the 600 MHz band
that would provide a 35 percent bidding
credit to businesses with average gross
revenues for the preceding three years
not exceeding $4 million.
168. Further, the NPRM seeks
comment on the Commission’s ability to
consider bidding preferences for other
types of DEs, entities that serve
unserved/underserved areas or areas
with persistent poverty, as well as
persons or entities that have overcome
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:06 Nov 13, 2014
Jkt 235001
disadvantages. The NPRM asks
commenters to specifically address the
statutory authority and judicial scrutiny
issues that may limit the Commission’s
ability to entertain recommendations to
alter the focus of its current bidding
preferences by offering bidding
preferences to entities based on other
criteria than business size.
169. The Commission expects that the
questions raised in the NPRM will
provide a meaningful opportunity to
evaluate whether its bidding credit
program continues to achieve the
Commission’s objectives. To facilitate
the Commission’s review, the NPRM
seeks concrete, specific, data-driven
feedback by commenters. In addition,
the NPRM invites commenters to
suggest other creative ideas that would
promote the Commission’s statutory
objectives, but emphasizes that for any
such proposals it is imperative to
provide ample supporting evidence.
170. DE Reporting Requirements. The
NPRM proposes to eliminate the DE
annual reporting requirement in 47 CFR
1.2110(n) and questions whether the
value of the information provided in
those reports outweighs the regulatory
burden that the reporting obligation
places on small businesses. The NPRM
seeks comment on this proposal. Among
other things, the NPRM asks if the
Commission adopts the proposal to
eliminate this annual reporting
requirement, whether it should amend
its rule for reporting eligibility events to
require that a small business must list
and summarize all existing agreements
to provide context each time it reports
a new eligibility event.
171. MMTC White Paper Requests. In
February 2014, MMTC submitted a
White Paper detailing several policy
recommendations to advance licensing
of spectrum to minority- and womenowned businesses. The NPRM raises
and addresses several of these issues
and seeks comments on the other
proposals that are not otherwise
addressed in the NPRM, and to the
extent that they relate to the
Commission’s competitive bidding
rules. The NPRM observes that certain
proposals appear to be outside the scope
of this proceeding and others may not
be needed in light of other changes
proposed in the NPRM. Toward that
end, the NPRM tentatively concludes
that the following MMTC proposals are
outside the scope of this proceeding,
which is focused on the Commission’s
competitive bidding rules, and thus will
not be addressed in the NPRM: (1)
Incorporating diversity and inclusion in
the Commission’s public interest
analysis of mergers and acquisitions and
secondary market spectrum
PO 00000
Frm 00062
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
transactions; and (2) supporting
increased funding for and statutory
amendments regarding the
Telecommunications Development
Fund.
172. Former Defaulter Rule. The
NPRM proposes changes to the
Commission’s former defaulter rule to
balance concerns that the current rule is
overly broad with the Commission’s
continued need to ensure that auction
bidders are financially reliable. The
NPRM seeks comment on revising the
rule to narrow the scope of the defaults
and delinquencies that will be
considered in determining whether or
not an auction participant is a former
defaulter. Specifically, the NPRM
proposes to exclude any cured default
on any Commission license or
delinquency on any non-tax debt owed
to any federal agency for which any of
the following criteria are met: (1) The
notice of the final payment deadline or
delinquency was received more than
seven years before the relevant shortform application deadline; (2) the
default or delinquency amounted to less
than $100,000; (3) the default or
delinquency was paid within two
quarters (i.e., 6 months) after receiving
the notice of the final payment deadline
or delinquency; or (4) the default or
delinquency was the subject of a legal
or arbitration proceeding that was cured
upon resolution of the proceeding.
Additionally, the NPRM seeks comment
on limiting the individuals and entities
that an applicant must consider when
determining its status as a former
defaulter.
173. Commonly Controlled Entities.
The NPRM proposes to codify an
established competitive bidding
procedure that prohibits the same
individual or entity from filing more
than one short-form application to
participate in an auction. The NPRM
also proposes a new rule that would
prevent entities that are exclusively
controlled by a single individual or set
of individuals from qualifying to bid on
licenses in the same or overlapping
geographic areas in a specific auction on
more than one short-form application.
These proposals seek to improve the
transparency and efficiency of the
auction process, by making clearer who
the qualified bidders actually are and
ensuring against the potential for
anticompetitive auction behavior. The
NPRM seeks comment on these
proposals and on specific alternatives to
address the Commission’s concern that
common control may allow the
controlling individual or set of
individuals to attempt to gain
advantages in the bidding process based
E:\FR\FM\14NOP1.SGM
14NOP1
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with PROPOSALS
Federal Register / Vol. 79, No. 220 / Friday, November 14, 2014 / Proposed Rules
on certain coordinated bidding actions
(e.g., tied bids, activity waivers).
174. Joint Bidding. The NPRM
initiates a review of the Commission’s
rules and policies governing joint
bidding and other arrangements in order
to ensure that they fulfill the
Commission’s statutory objectives, given
the changes in the mobile wireless
marketplace since the initial adoption of
the bidding rules two decades ago, and
the increasing importance of spectrum
for service providers to meet consumer
demand for mobile wireless services.
The NPRM seeks comment on the
Commission’s tentative conclusions that
it would be in the public interest to
retain the current rules governing joint
bidding arrangements among nonnationwide providers and to prohibit
joint bidding arrangements among
nationwide providers. Additionally, the
NPRM seeks comment on whether the
Commission should revise any of its
current rules as applied to arrangements
between nationwide providers and other
entities, including its rules governing
short-form applications. Further, the
NPRM seeks comment on whether any
revisions to the Commission’s rules
governing long-form applications are
necessary in light of the Commission’s
consideration of the potential harms and
benefits of joint bidding and other
arrangements.
175. Miscellaneous Part 1 Revisions.
In addition to changes that would
implement the foregoing proposals, the
NPRM proposes changes to two of the
Commission’s part 1, Subpart Q, rules,
47 CFR 1.2111 and 1.2112. 47 CFR
1.2111—The NPRM proposes to
eliminate two provisions of this rule: (1)
47 CFR 1.2111(a), under which
applicants for assignments or transfers
during the first three years of a license
term must provide the Commission with
detailed contract and marketing
information, and (2) 47 CFR 1.2111(b),
a never-used unjust enrichment
payment requirement for broadband
PCS C and F block set-aside licenses.
47 CFR 1.2112—The NPRM’s proposed
changes to this rule clarify the auction
application requirements for reporting
an entity’s percentage ownership in the
applicant and in FCC-regulated entities.
The NPRM proposes further changes to
specify application requirements for
bidding consortia. The NPRM also
proposes to correct two errors in the
rule caused by the inadvertent
substitution of an incorrect paragraph in
the Code of Federal Regulations
publication of the rule for the correct
one published in the Federal Register
summary of the DE Second Report and
Order. The first error was the addition
of a requirement that DE short-form
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:06 Nov 13, 2014
Jkt 235001
applicants list and summarize all their
agreements that support their DE
eligibility, a requirement that the
Commission intended to apply only to
long-form applicants. The NPRM
proposes to delete the requirement with
respect to the short-form. The second
error was the deletion of a requirement
that DE short-form applicants list the
parties with which they have lease or
resale arrangements for any of the DE
applicants’ spectrum. The NPRM
proposes to reinstate this requirement.
176. The NPRM seeks comments on
these proposals. In addition, the NPRM
notes that the Commission intends,
when it resolves the issues raised in the
NPRM, to resolve long standing
petitions for reconsideration to the
Commission’s part 1 competitive
bidding rules.
4. Steps Taken To Minimize Significant
Economic Impact on Small Entities, and
Significant Alternatives Considered
177. The RFA requires an agency to
describe any significant alternatives that
it has considered in reaching its
proposed approach, which may include
the following four alternatives (among
others): (1) The establishment of
differing compliance or reporting
requirements or timetables that take into
account the resources available to small
entities; (2) the clarification,
consolidation, or simplification of
compliance or reporting requirements
under the rule for small entities; (3) the
use of performance, rather than design,
standards; and (4) an exemption from
coverage of the rule, or any part thereof,
for small entities.
178. If adopted, the NPRM’s proposed
approach to evaluating attribution and
establishing small business eligibility
could provide small businesses with
greater opportunities to participate in
the provision of spectrum-based
services. Moreover, insofar as the
NPRM’s proposals should allow small
businesses greater flexibility to engage
in business ventures that include
increased forms of leasing and other
spectrum use arrangements, the
Commission anticipates that the
combined intent of the proposals should
increase the potential sources of
revenue for the small business and
decrease the likelihood that it would be
subject to undue influence by any
particular user of a single license. The
NPRM’s proposed two-pronged
approach to establishing small business
eligibility would also ensure that a
licensee retains control of all licenses
for which it seeks bidding credits, while
providing greater flexibility for any
acquired without such benefits. Further,
the proposal to eliminate the AMR rule
PO 00000
Frm 00063
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
68199
and to clarify how spectrum manager
leasing rules apply to DEs should allow
small businesses greater certainty to
participate in secondary markets
transactions.
179. The NPRM’s proposed increases
in the gross revenues thresholds that
define the three tiers of small businesses
in the part 1 schedule by which the
Commission provides the corresponding
available bidding credits would
encourage small business participation
in spectrum license auctions. The
proposed gross revenues thresholds are
intended to more accurately reflect what
constitutes a ‘‘small business’’ in today’s
marketplace, taking into consideration
the relative size of the large, national
providers. This proposal will provide an
economic benefit to small entities by
making it easier to acquire spectrum
licenses. Moreover, the NPRM’s
proposal to repeal the DE reporting
requirement would eliminate the
burden on DEs to submit annual reports.
180. The proposed changes to the part
1 rules will apply to all entities in the
same manner the Commission will
apply these changes uniformly to all
entities that choose to participate in
spectrum license auctions. The
Commission believes that applying the
same rules equally to all entities in
these contexts promotes fairness. The
Commission does not believe that the
limited costs and/or administrative
burdens associated with the rule
revisions will unduly burden small
entities. In fact, many of the proposed
rule revisions clarify the Commission’s
competitive bidding rules, including
short-form application requirements, as
well as reduce reporting requirements.
181. Finally, the NPRM’s joint
bidding proposals are intended to
preserve and promote robust
competition in the mobile wireless
marketplace and facilitate competition
among bidders at auction, including
small entities. These proposals provide
potential bidders with greater clarity
regarding the types of joint bidding
arrangements that would be permissible.
In addition, the NPRM’s proposal to
retain its current rules for joint bidding
arrangements among non-nationwide
providers would maintain flexibility for
small businesses to enter into such
arrangements.
List of Subjects
47 CFR Part 1
Administrative practice and
procedure.
47 CFR Part 27
Communications common carriers,
Radio.
E:\FR\FM\14NOP1.SGM
14NOP1
68200
Federal Register / Vol. 79, No. 220 / Friday, November 14, 2014 / Proposed Rules
Federal Communications Commission.
Marlene H. Dortch,
Secretary.
Proposed Rules
For the reasons discussed in the
preamble, the Federal Communications
Commission proposes to amend 47 CFR
Parts 1 and 27 as follows:
PART 1—PRACTICE AND
PROCEDURE
1. The authority citation for part 1
continues to read as follows:
■
Authority: 15 U.S.C. 79 et seq.; 47 U.S.C.
151, 154(i), 154(j), 155, 157, 225, 227, 303(r),
309, 1403, 1404, 1451, and 1452.
2. Section 1.2105 is amended by
revising paragraphs (a)(2)(xi) and (b)(1)
to read as follows:
(ii) If (A) An individual or entity
submits multiple applications in a
single auction; or
(B) Entities commonly controlled by
the same individual or same set of
individuals submit applications for any
set of licenses in the same or
overlapping geographic areas in a single
auction; then only one of such
applications may be deemed complete,
and the other such application(s) will be
deemed incomplete, such applicants
will not be found qualified to bid, and
the associated upfront payment(s), if
paid, will be returned.
*
*
*
*
*
■ 3. Section 1.2106 is amended by
revising paragraph (a) to read as follows:
■
§ 1.2105 Bidding application and
certification procedures; prohibition of
certain communications.
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with PROPOSALS
*
*
*
*
*
(a) * * *
(2) * * *
(xi) An attached statement made
under penalty of perjury indicating
whether or not the applicant has been
in default on any Commission license or
has been delinquent on any non-tax
debt owed to any Federal agency. For
purposes of this certification, an
applicant may exclude from
consideration as a former default any
default on a Commission license or
delinquency on non-tax debt to any
Federal agency that has been resolved
and meets any of the following criteria:
(A) The notice of the final payment
deadline or delinquency was received
more than seven years before the shortform application deadline;
(B) The default or delinquency
amounted to less than $100,000;
(C) The default or delinquency was
paid within two quarters (i.e., 6 months)
after receiving the notice of the final
payment deadline or delinquency; or
(D) The default or delinquency was
the subject of a legal or arbitration
proceeding that was cured upon
resolution of the proceeding.
*
*
*
*
*
(b) Modification and Dismissal of
Short-Form Application (FCC Form
175).
(1)(i) Any short-form application (FCC
Form 175) that does not contain all of
the certifications required pursuant to
this section is unacceptable for filing
and cannot be corrected subsequent to
the applicable filing deadline. The
application will be deemed incomplete,
the applicant will not be found qualified
to bid, and the upfront payment, if paid,
will be returned.
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:06 Nov 13, 2014
Jkt 235001
§ 1.2106
Submission of upfront payments.
(a) The Commission may require
applicants for licenses subject to
competitive bidding to submit an
upfront payment. In that event, the
amount of the upfront payment and the
procedures for submitting it will be set
forth in a Public Notice. Any auction
applicant that, pursuant to
§ 1.2105(a)(2)(xi), certifies that it is a
former defaulter must submit an upfront
payment equal to 50 percent more than
that set for each particular license. No
interest will be paid on upfront
payments.
*
*
*
*
*
■ 4. Amend § 1.2110 as follows:
■ A. Revise paragraph (b)(1)(i) and (ii);
■ B. Remove paragraph (b)(3)(iv);
■ C. Revise paragraphs (f)(2) and (j);
■ D. Remove paragraph (n);
■ E. Redesignate paragraphs (o) and (p)
as paragraphs (n) and (o)
The additions and revisions read as
follows:
§ 1.2110
Designated entities.
*
*
*
*
*
(b) * * *
(1) * * *
(i) The gross revenues of the applicant
(or licensee), its affiliates, its controlling
interests, and the affiliates of its
controlling interests shall be attributed
to the applicant (or licensee) and
considered on a cumulative basis and
aggregated for purposes of determining
whether the applicant (or licensee) is
eligible for status as a small business,
very small business, or entrepreneur, as
those terms are defined in the servicespecific rules. An applicant seeking
status as a small business, very small
business, or entrepreneur, as those
terms are defined in the service-specific
rules, must disclose on its short- and
long-form applications, separately and
in the aggregate, the gross revenues for
each of the previous three years of the
applicant (or licensee), its affiliates, its
PO 00000
Frm 00064
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
controlling interests, and the affiliates of
its controlling interests.
(ii) If applicable, pursuant to § 24.709
of this chapter, the total assets of the
applicant (or licensee), its affiliates, its
controlling interests, and the affiliates of
its controlling interests shall be
attributed to the applicant (or licensee)
and considered on a cumulative basis
and aggregated for purposes of
determining whether the applicant (or
licensee) is eligible for status as an
entrepreneur. An applicant seeking
status as an entrepreneur must disclose
on its short- and long-form applications,
separately and in the aggregate, the
gross revenues for each of the previous
two years of the applicant (or licensee),
its affiliates, its controlling interests,
and the affiliates of its controlling
interests.
*
*
*
*
*
(f) * * *
(2) Size of bidding credits. A winning
bidder that qualifies as a small business
may use the following bidding credits
corresponding to its respective average
gross revenues for the preceding 3 years:
(i) Businesses with average gross
revenues for the preceding 3 years not
exceeding $4 million are eligible for
bidding credits of 35 percent;
(ii) Businesses with average gross
revenues for the preceding 3 years not
exceeding $20 million are eligible for
bidding credits of 25 percent; and
(iii) Businesses with average gross
revenues for the preceding 3 years not
exceeding $55 million are eligible for
bidding credits of 15 percent.
*
*
*
*
*
(j) Designated entities must describe
on their long-form applications how
they satisfy the requirements for
eligibility for designated entity status,
and must list and summarize on their
long form applications all agreements
that affect designated entity status such
as partnership agreements, shareholder
agreements, management agreements,
spectrum leasing arrangements,
spectrum resale (including wholesale)
arrangements, and all other agreements
including oral agreements, establishing
as applicable, de facto or de jure control
of the entity. Designated entities also
must provide the date(s) on which they
entered into of the agreements listed. In
addition, designated entities must file
with their long-form applications a copy
of each such agreement. In order to
enable the Commission to audit
designated entity eligibility on an
ongoing basis, designated entities that
are awarded eligibility must, for the
term of the license, maintain at their
facilities or with their designated agents
the lists, summaries, dates and copies of
E:\FR\FM\14NOP1.SGM
14NOP1
Federal Register / Vol. 79, No. 220 / Friday, November 14, 2014 / Proposed Rules
agreements required to be identified and
provided to the Commission pursuant to
this paragraph and to § 1.2114.
*
*
*
*
*
■ 5. Section 1.2111 is revised to read as
follows:
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with PROPOSALS
§ 1.2111 Assignment or transfer of control:
unnjust enrichment.
(a) Unjust enrichment payment:
installment financing.
(1) If a licensee that utilizes
installment financing under this section
seeks to assign or transfer control of its
license to an entity not meeting the
eligibility standards for installment
payments, the licensee must make full
payment of the remaining unpaid
principal and any unpaid interest
accrued through the date of assignment
or transfer as a condition of approval.
(2) If a licensee that utilizes
installment financing under this section
seeks to make any change in ownership
structure that would result in the
licensee’s losing eligibility for
installment payments, the licensee shall
first seek Commission approval and
must make full payment of the
remaining unpaid principal and any
unpaid interest accrued through the
date of such change as a condition of
approval. A licensee’s (or other
attributable entity’s) increased gross
revenues or increased total assets due to
nonattributable equity investments, debt
financing, revenue from operations or
other investments, business
development or expanded service shall
not be considered to result in the
licensee losing eligibility for installment
payments.
(3) If a licensee seeks to make any
change in ownership that would result
in the licensee’s qualifying for a less
favorable installment plan under this
section, the licensee shall seek
Commission approval and must adjust
its payment plan to reflect its new
eligibility status. A licensee may not
switch its payment plan to a more
favorable plan.
(b) Unjust enrichment payment:
bidding credits.
(1) A licensee that utilizes a bidding
credit, and that during the initial term
seeks to assign or transfer control of a
license to an entity that does not meet
the eligibility criteria for a bidding
credit, will be required to reimburse the
U.S. Government for the amount of the
bidding credit, plus interest based on
the rate for ten year U.S. Treasury
obligations applicable on the date the
license was granted, as a condition of
Commission approval of the assignment
or transfer. If, within the initial term of
the license, a licensee that utilizes a
bidding credit seeks to assign or transfer
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:06 Nov 13, 2014
Jkt 235001
control of a license to an entity that is
eligible for a lower bidding credit, the
difference between the bidding credit
obtained by the assigning party and the
bidding credit for which the acquiring
party would qualify, plus interest based
on the rate for ten year U.S. treasury
obligations applicable on the date the
license is granted, must be paid to the
U.S. Government as a condition of
Commission approval of the assignment
or transfer. If, within the initial term of
the license, a licensee that utilizes a
bidding credit makes any ownership
change or enters into any agreement that
would result in the licensee’s losing
eligibility for a bidding credit (or
qualifying for a lower bidding credit),
the amount of the bidding credit (or the
difference between the bidding credit
originally obtained and the bidding
credit for which the licensee would
qualify after restructuring or under the
agreement), plus interest based on the
rate for ten year U.S. treasury
obligations applicable on the date the
license is granted, must be paid to the
U.S. Government as a condition of
Commission approval of the assignment
or transfer or of a reportable eligibility
event (see § 1.2114).
(2) Payment schedule.
(i) The amount of payments made
pursuant to paragraph (b)(1) of this
section will be reduced over time as
follows:
(A) A loss of eligibility in the first two
years of the license term will result in
a forfeiture of 100 percent of the value
of the bidding credit (or in the case of
very small businesses transferring to
small businesses, 100 percent of the
difference between the bidding credit
received by the former and the bidding
credit for which the latter is eligible);
(B) A loss of eligibility in year 3 of the
license term will result in a forfeiture of
75 percent of the value of the bidding
credit (or in the case of eligibility
changing to qualify for a lower bidding
credit, 75 percent of the difference
between the bidding credit received and
the bidding credit for which it is
eligible);
(C) A loss of eligibility in year 4 of the
license term will result in a forfeiture of
50 percent of the value of the bidding
credit (or in the case of eligibility
changing to qualify for a lower bidding
credit, 50 percent of the difference
between the bidding credit received and
the bidding credit for which it is
eligible);
(D) A loss of eligibility in year 5 of the
license term will result in a forfeiture of
25 percent of the value of the bidding
credit (or in the case of eligibility
changing to qualify for a lower bidding
credit, 25 percent of the difference
PO 00000
Frm 00065
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
68201
between the bidding credit received and
the bidding credit for which it is
eligible); and
(E) For a loss of eligibility in year 6
or thereafter, there will be no payment.
(ii) These payments will have to be
paid to the United States Treasury as a
condition of approval of the assignment,
transfer, ownership change or reportable
eligibility event (see § 1.2114).
(c) Unjust enrichment: partitioning
and disaggregation—
(1) Installment payments. Licensees
making installment payments, that
partition their licenses or disaggregate
their spectrum to entities not meeting
the eligibility standards for installment
payments, will be subject to the
provisions concerning unjust
enrichment as set forth in this section.
(2) Bidding credits. Licensees that
received a bidding credit that partition
their licenses or disaggregate their
spectrum to entities not meeting the
eligibility standards for such a bidding
credit, will be subject to the provisions
concerning unjust enrichment as set
forth in this section.
(3) Apportioning unjust enrichment
payments. Unjust enrichment payments
for partitioned license areas shall be
calculated based upon the ratio of the
population of the partitioned license
area to the overall population of the
license area and by utilizing the most
recent Census data. Unjust enrichment
payments for disaggregated spectrum
shall be calculated based upon the ratio
of the amount of spectrum disaggregated
to the amount of spectrum held by the
licensee.
■ 6. Section 1.2112 is amended by
revising paragraphs (a)(7), (b)(1)(iii) and
(iv); adding paragraph (b)(1)(v); and
revising paragraph (b)(2)(ii), (iii) and (v)
to read as follows:
§ 1.2112 Ownership disclosure
requirements for applications.
(a) * * *
(7) List any FCC-regulated entity or
applicant for an FCC license, in which
the applicant or any of the parties
identified in paragraphs (a)(1) through
(a)(5) of this section holds a 10 percent
or greater ownership interest, regardless
of the type of business entity, including
both active and passive interests. This
list must include a description of each
such entity’s principal business and a
description of each such entity’s
relationship to the applicant (e.g.,
Company A owns 10 percent of
Company B (the applicant) and 10
percent of Company C, then Companies
A and C must be listed on Company B’s
application, where C is an FCC licensee
and/or license applicant).
(b) * * *
E:\FR\FM\14NOP1.SGM
14NOP1
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with PROPOSALS
68202
Federal Register / Vol. 79, No. 220 / Friday, November 14, 2014 / Proposed Rules
(1) * * *
(iii) List all parties with which the
applicant has entered into arrangements
for the spectrum lease or resale
(including wholesale arrangements) of
any of the capacity of any of the
applicant’s spectrum.
(iv) List separately and in the
aggregate the gross revenues, computed
in accordance with § 1.2110, for each of
the following: The applicant, its
affiliates, its controlling interests, and
the affiliates of its controlling interests;
and if a consortium of small businesses,
the members comprising the
consortium.
(v) If applying as a consortium under
§ 1.2110(b)(3)(i), provide the
information in paragraphs (b)(1)(i)
through (iv) separately for each member
of the consortium.
(2) * * *
(ii) List any FCC-regulated entity or
applicant for an FCC license, in which
any controlling interest of the applicant
owns a 10 percent or greater interest or
a total of 10 percent or more of any class
of stock, warrants, options or debt
securities. This list must include a
description of each such entity’s
principal business and a description of
each such entity’s relationship to the
applicant;
(iii) List and summarize all
agreements or instruments (with
appropriate references to specific
provisions in the text of such
agreements and instruments) that
support the applicant’s eligibility as a
small business under the applicable
designated entity provisions, including
the establishment of de facto or de jure
control. Such agreements and
instruments include articles of
incorporation and by-laws, partnership
agreements, shareholder agreements,
voting or other trust agreements,
management agreements, franchise
agreements, spectrum leasing
arrangements, spectrum resale
(including wholesale) arrangements,
and any other relevant agreements
(including letters of intent), oral or
written;
*
*
*
*
*
(v) List separately and in the aggregate
the gross revenues, computed in
accordance with § 1.2110, for each of
the following: The applicant, its
affiliates, its controlling interests, and
affiliates of its controlling interests; and
if a consortium of small businesses, the
members comprising the consortium;
and
*
*
*
*
*
■ 7. Section 1.9020 is amended by
revising paragraph (d)(4) to read as
follows:
VerDate Sep<11>2014
17:06 Nov 13, 2014
Jkt 235001
§ 1.9020 Spectrum manager leasing
arrangements.
*
*
*
*
*
(d) * * *
(4) Designated entity/entrepreneur
rules. A licensee that holds a license
pursuant to small business and/or
entrepreneur provisions (see § 1.2110
and § 24.709 of this chapter) and
continues to be subject to unjust
enrichment requirements (see § 1.2111
and § 24.714 of this chapter) and/or
transfer restrictions (see § 24.839 of this
chapter) may enter into a spectrum
manager leasing arrangement with a
spectrum lessee, regardless of whether
the spectrum lessee meets the
Commission’s designated entity
eligibility requirements (see § 1.2110) or
its entrepreneur eligibility requirements
to hold certain C and F block licenses
in the broadband personal
communications services (see § 1.2110
and § 24.709 of this chapter), so long as
the spectrum manager leasing
arrangement does not result in the
spectrum lessee’s becoming a
‘‘controlling interest’’ or ‘‘affiliate’’ (see
§ 1.2110) of the licensee such that the
licensee would lose its eligibility as a
designated entity or entrepreneur.
*
*
*
*
*
PART 27—MISCELLANEOUS
WIRELESS COMMUNICATIONS
SERVICES
8. The authority citation for part 27
continues to read as follows:
■
Authority: 47 U.S.C. 154, 301, 302a, 303,
307, 309, 332, 336, 337, 1403, 1404, 1451,
and 1452, unless otherwise noted.
9. Section 27.1301 is amended by
removing the undesignated introductory
text and revising paragraph (a) to read
as follows:
■
§ 27.1301 Designated entities in the 600
MHz band.
(a) Eligibility for small business
provisions.
(1) A small business is an entity that,
together with its affiliates, its
controlling interests, the affiliates of its
controlling interests, and the entities
with which it has an attributable
material relationship, has average gross
revenues not exceeding $55 million for
the preceding three (3) years.
(2) A very small business is an entity
that, together with its affiliates, its
controlling interests, the affiliates of its
controlling interests, and the entities
with which it has an attributable
material relationship, has average gross
PO 00000
Frm 00066
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
revenues not exceeding $20 million for
the preceding three (3) years.
*
*
*
*
*
[FR Doc. 2014–26924 Filed 11–13–14; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6712–01–P
DEPARTMENT OF COMMERCE
National Oceanic and Atmospheric
Administration
50 CFR Part 648
[Docket No. 140902739–4739–01]
RIN 0648–BE49
Fisheries of the Northeastern United
States; Atlantic Mackerel, Squid, and
Butterfish Fisheries; Specifications
and Management Measures
National Marine Fisheries
Service (NMFS), National Oceanic and
Atmospheric Administration (NOAA),
Commerce.
ACTION: Proposed rule, request for
comments.
AGENCY:
NMFS proposes 2015
specifications and management
measures for Atlantic mackerel, 2015–
2017 specifications for Illex squid,
2015–2017 specifications for longfin
squid, and 2015–2017 specifications for
butterfish. This action also proposes
simplifying the butterfish fishery
closure mechanism. These proposed
specifications and management
measures are intended to promote the
utilization and conservation of the
Atlantic mackerel, squid, and butterfish
resources.
DATES: Public comments must be
received no later than 5 p.m., eastern
standard time, on December 15, 2014.
ADDRESSES: Copies of supporting
documents used by the Mid-Atlantic
Fishery Management Council, including
the Environmental Assessment (EA) and
Regulatory Impact Review (RIR)/Initial
Regulatory Flexibility Analysis (IRFA),
are available from: Dr. Christopher M.
Moore, Executive Director, Mid-Atlantic
Fishery Management Council, Suite 201,
800 N. State Street, Dover, DE 19901.
The EA/RIR/IRFA is accessible via the
Internet at https://h https://
www.greateratlantic.fisheries.noaa.gov/.
You may submit comments, identified
by NOAA–NMFS–2014–0139, by any
one of the following methods:
• Electronic Submission: Submit all
electronic public comments via the
Federal e-Rulemaking Portal
www.regulations.gov. To submit
comments via the e-Rulemaking Portal,
first click the ‘‘submit a comment’’ icon,
then enter NOAA–NMFS–2014–0139 in
SUMMARY:
E:\FR\FM\14NOP1.SGM
14NOP1
Agencies
[Federal Register Volume 79, Number 220 (Friday, November 14, 2014)]
[Proposed Rules]
[Pages 68172-68202]
From the Federal Register Online via the Government Printing Office [www.gpo.gov]
[FR Doc No: 2014-26924]
=======================================================================
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION
47 CFR Parts 1 and 27
[RM-11395, GN Docket No. 12-268, WT Docket Nos. 14-170, 05-211; FCC 14-
146]
Updating Competitive Bidding Rules; Expanding the Economic and
Innovation Opportunities of Spectrum Through Incentive Auctions;
Implementation of the Commercial Spectrum Enhancement Act
AGENCY: Federal Communications Commission.
ACTION: Proposed rule.
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
SUMMARY: This Notice of Proposed Rulemaking (NPRM) seeks comment on the
revision of certain competitive bidding rules and provides notice of
the Commission's intention to resolve longstanding petitions for
reconsideration.
DATES: Comments are due on or before December 29, 2014 and reply
comments are due on or before January 20, 2015.
ADDRESSES: All filings in response to the NPRM must refer to GN Docket
No. 12-268 and WT Docket Nos. 14-170 and 05-211. The Commission
strongly encourages parties to develop responses to the NPRM that
adhere to the organization and structure of the NPRM. Comments may be
filed using the Commission's Electronic Comment Filing System (ECFS):
[ssquf] Electronic Filers: Comments may be filed electronically
using the Internet by accessing ECFS: https://fjallfoss.fcc.gov/ecfs2.
[ssquf] Paper Filers: Parties who choose to file by paper must file
an original and one copy of each filing. If more than one docket or
rulemaking number appears in the caption of this proceeding, filers
must submit two additional copies for each additional docket or
rulemaking number.
Filings can be sent by hand or messenger delivery, by commercial
overnight courier, or by first-class or overnight U.S. Postal Service
mail. All filings must be addressed to the Commission's Secretary,
Office of the Secretary, Federal Communications Commission.
All hand-delivered or messenger-delivered paper filings for the
Commission's Secretary must be delivered to FCC Headquarters at 445
12th Street SW., Room TW-A325, Washington, DC 20554. The filing hours
are 8:00 a.m. to 7:00 p.m. All hand deliveries must be held together
with rubber bands or fasteners. Any envelopes and boxes must be
disposed of before entering the building.
Commercial overnight mail (other than U.S. Postal Service Express
Mail and Priority Mail) must be sent to 9300 East Hampton Drive,
Capitol Heights, MD 20743.
U.S. Postal Service first-class, Express, and Priority mail must be
addressed to 445 12th Street SW., Washington, DC 20554.
People with Disabilities: To request materials in accessible
formats for people with disabilities (braille, large print, electronic
files, or audio format), send an email to fcc504@fcc.gov or call the
Consumer & Governmental Affairs Bureau at 202-418-0530 (voice), 202-
418-0432 (TTY).
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: Wireless Telecommunications Bureau,
Auctions and Spectrum Access Division: Kathryn Hinton at (202) 418-
0660.
[[Page 68173]]
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: This is a summary of the Competitive Bidding
NPRM released on October 10, 2014. The complete text of the Competitive
Bidding NPRM is available for public inspection and copying from 8:00
a.m. to 4:30 p.m. Eastern Time (ET) Monday through Thursday or from
8:00 a.m. to 11:30 a.m. ET on Fridays in the FCC Reference Information
Center, 445 12th Street SW., Room CY-A257, Washington, DC 20554. The
Competitive Bidding NPRM may be purchased from the Commission's
duplicating contractor, Best Copy and Printing, Inc. (BCPI), 445 12th
Street SW., Room CY-B402, Washington, DC 20554, telephone 202-488-5300,
facsimile 202-488-5563, or by contacting BCPI on its Web site: https://www.BCPIWEB.com. When ordering documents from BCPI, please provide the
appropriate FCC document number, for example, FCC 14-146. The complete
text is also available on the Commission's Web site at https://wireless.fcc.gov, or by using the search function on the ECFS Web page
at https://www.fcc.gov/cgb/ecfs.
Initial Paperwork Reduction Act of 1995 Analysis
The NPRM contains proposed new or modified information collection
requirements. The Commission, as part of its continuing effort to
reduce paperwork burdens, invites the general public and the Office of
Management and Budget (OMB) to comment on the information collection
requirements contained in this document, as required by the Paperwork
Reduction Act of 1995, Public Law 104-13. In addition, pursuant to the
Small Business Paperwork Relief Act of 2002, Public Law 107-198, see 44
U.S.C. 3506(c)(4), the Commission seeks specific comment on how it
might further reduce the information collection burden for small
business concerns with fewer than 25 employees.
I. Introduction
1. The Commission proposes to reform some of its general part 1
rules governing competitive bidding for spectrum licenses to reflect
changes in the marketplace, including the challenges faced by new
entrants. The Commission's proposals also advance the statutory
directive to ensure that small businesses, rural telephone companies,
and businesses owned by members of minority groups and women
(collectively, designated entities or DEs) are given the opportunity to
participate in the provision of spectrum-based services, and fulfill
the commitment the Commission made in the Broadcast Television Spectrum
Incentive Auction Report & Order. Expanding the Economic and Innovation
Opportunities of Spectrum Through Incentive Auctions, 79 FR 48442, Aug.
15, 2014. Together these proposals will assure that the Commission's
part 1 rules continue to promote the Commission's fundamental statutory
objectives. The Commission expects to act on the issues it raises here
soon enough to allow all parties to account for any changes while
planning for the Broadcast Television Spectrum Incentive Auction
(hereinafter, Incentive Auction or BIA).
2. In the Competitive Bidding NPRM, the Commission proposes to: (1)
Provide small businesses greater opportunity to participate in the
provision of a wide range of spectrum-based services by modifying the
Commission's eligibility requirements, updating the standardized
schedule of small business sizes, and eliminating duplicative reporting
requirements, while also seeking comment on whether to strengthen its
rules to prevent the unjust enrichment of ineligible entities; (2)
Amend the Commission's former defaulter rule to balance concerns that
the current rule is overly broad with the Commission's continued need
to ensure that auction bidders are financially reliable; (3) Codify an
established competitive bidding procedure that prohibits the same
individual or entity from becoming qualified to bid on the basis of
more than one short-form (FCC Form 175) application in a specific
auction; (4) Prevent entities that are exclusively controlled by a
single individual or set of individuals from becoming qualified to bid
on overlapping licenses based on more than one short-form application
in a specific auction; and (5) Retain the current rules governing joint
bidding arrangements among non-nationwide providers and prohibit joint
bidding arrangements among nationwide providers.
3. The Commission also provides notice of its intention to resolve
long standing petitions for reconsideration and proposes necessary
clean-up revisions to its part 1 competitive bidding rules.
II. Eligibility for Bidding Credits
4. In establishing the Commission's auction authority, Congress
vested the Commission with broad discretion in balancing a number of
competing objectives. These included, among other things, special
provisions to ensure that DEs, including small businesses, have the
opportunity to participate at auction and in the provision of spectrum-
based services. Section 309(j)(4)(D) of the Communications Act (the
Act) requires that when the Commission prescribes regulations in
designing systems of competitive bidding, it shall ``ensure that small
businesses, rural telephone companies, and businesses owned by members
of minority groups and women are given the opportunity to participate
in the provision of spectrum-based services, and, for such purposes,
consider the use of . . . bidding preferences.'' In addition, the
statute directs that in designing such systems of competitive bidding,
the Commission shall seek to promote ``economic opportunity and
competition . . . by avoiding excessive concentration of licenses and
by disseminating licenses among a wide variety of applicants, including
small businesses, rural telephone companies, and businesses owned by
members of minority groups and women.'' At the same time, the Act
requires the Commission to ``prevent unjust enrichment as a result of
the methods employed to issue licenses. . . .''
5. The Commission's challenge in providing opportunities to small
businesses and entrepreneurs pursuant to these provisions has always
been to find a reasonable balance between the competing goals of
affording such entities reasonable flexibility to obtain the capital
necessary to participate in the provision of spectrum-based services
and effectively preventing the unjust enrichment of ineligible
entities. See Implementation of the Commercial Spectrum Enhancement Act
and Modernization of the Commission's Competitive Bidding Rules and
Procedures, 71 FR 26245, May 4, 2006 (DE Second Report and Order). Over
the two-decade span of the auctions program, the Commission has
periodically modified its rules to achieve the right balance given
changing circumstances in the wireless industry.
6. The Commission takes the opportunity to consider whether its
rules continue to serve their intended purposes and the public interest
in an evolving mobile wireless marketplace. In the past decade, the
rapid adoption of smartphones and tablet computers and the widespread
use of mobile applications, combined with the increasing deployment of
high-speed 3G and now 4G technologies, have driven significantly more
intensive use of mobile networks. This progression from the provision
of mobile voice services to the provision of mobile broadband services
has increased the need for access to spectrum. In addition, in the past
decade, the number of small and regional mobile wireless service
providers has significantly decreased, yet regional and local service
providers continue to offer consumers additional
[[Page 68174]]
choices in the areas they serve. As the costs of spectrum and network
deployment have increased in the last 20 years, especially for small
and new entrants, access to capital for acquiring licenses is critical
for these providers to take advantage of different opportunities to
participate in the provision of spectrum-based services, including
through facilities-based deployment, spectrum leasing, and mobile
virtual network operator arrangements.
7. The Commission addresses the concerns of parties that argue that
its current rules inhibit, rather than foster, the inclusion of small
businesses in the wireless marketplace. The Commission offers proposals
to increase the opportunities for small businesses to become spectrum
licensees. At the same time, the Commission remains mindful of its
responsibility to ensure that benefits are provided only to qualifying
entities and seeks comment on modifying its current unjust enrichment
rules.
8. As a first step in reassessing how the Commission determines
small business eligibility, the Commission proposes to repeal the
attributable material relationship (AMR) rule and to re-examine the
need for the related decade-old policy that has limited small
businesses seeking bidding credits to providing primarily retail,
facilities-based service directly to the public with each of their
licenses. The Commission proposes to instead adopt a more flexible
approach under which it would evaluate small business eligibility on a
license-by-license basis, using a two-pronged test. Under this
proposal, the Commission would apply existing rules requiring
attribution of controlling interests in, and affiliates of, a small
business venture to determine whether the applicant: (1) Meets the
applicable small business size standard, and (2) retains control over
the spectrum associated with the individual licenses for which it seeks
benefits. The Commission further proposes to modify the language of 47
CFR 1.9020 to make clear that DE lessors may fully engage in spectrum
manager leasing under the same de facto control standard as non-DE
lessors. With these proposals, the Commission revisits its statutory
mandate under 47 U.S.C. 309(j)(4)(D) ``to ensure that small businesses,
rural telephone companies, and businesses owned by members of minority
groups and women are given the opportunity to participate in the
provision of spectrum-based services'' in light of today's wireless
marketplace. Alternatively, the Commission also seeks comment on
retaining the policy and/or some variation of the AMR rule. The
Commission also asks whether it should revisit its unjust enrichment
rules to assure that the Commission maintains the right balance
considering its responsibility to safeguard the award of small business
benefits to only eligible entities.
9. The Commission also proposes to modify the generally applicable
schedule of small business size standards and bidding credits, which
has remained unchanged in the 17 years since it was first adopted. The
goal of these proposals is to encourage small business participation in
spectrum license auctions and to ensure that the Commission's gross
revenue definitions accurately reflect what constitutes a ``small
business'' in today's marketplace, taking into consideration the
relative size of the large, national providers. Specifically, the
Commission proposes revisions to its small business definitions and
seeks comment on whether to change the bidding credit percentages that
would apply to those definitions. The Commission also seeks comment on
whether to offer alternative bidding preferences to entities based on
criteria other than business size by revenue.
10. Additionally, the Commission proposes to repeal the DE annual
reporting requirement. The Commission questions whether the value of
the information provided in those reports outweighs the regulatory
burden that the reporting obligation places on small businesses.
11. Collectively, these proposals seek to update the Commission's
rules to reflect that small businesses need greater opportunities to
gain access to capital so that they may have an opportunity to
participate in the provision of spectrum-based services in today's
communications marketplace. The Commission recognizes that high capital
costs associated with building and operating wireless broadband
networks may require small businesses to find alternative revenue
streams, including through secondary markets, so that they have an
opportunity to acquire licenses at auction and participate in the
provision of spectrum-based services. The Commission anticipates that
by revising its rules to allow small businesses to take advantage of
the same opportunities to utilize their spectrum capacity and gain
access to capital as those afforded to larger licensees, the Commission
can better achieve its statutory directives. The Commission nonetheless
remains mindful of its obligation to prevent unjust enrichment of
ineligible entities. The Commission describes and seeks comment on each
of its specific proposals.
A. Attribution Rules and Small Business Policies
12. Background. As its principal means of fulfilling the statutory
goals for DEs, the Commission makes auction bidding credits available
to eligible small businesses. A small business is eligible for bidding
credits if its gross revenues, in combination with those of its
``attributable'' interest holders, fall below applicable service-
specific financial caps. Since 2000, the Commission has applied a
``controlling interest'' standard to all services when making these
attribution determinations in the small business context. Under this
standard, the Commission attributes to an applicant the gross revenues
of the applicant, its controlling interests, its affiliates, and the
affiliates of the applicant's controlling interests. A ``controlling
interest'' includes individuals or entities, or groups of individuals
or entities, that have control of the applicant under the principles of
either de jure or de facto control. Affiliates include entities or
individuals that directly or indirectly control or have the power to
control the applicant, directly or indirectly are controlled by the
applicant, directly or indirectly are controlled by a third party that
also controls the applicant, or have an ``identity of interest'' with
the applicant.
13. In adopting secondary markets rules in the 2004 Secondary
Markets Second Report and Order, the Commission sought to expand and
enhance secondary markets to permit spectrum to flow more freely among
users and uses in response to economic demand, to the extent consistent
with its public interest objectives. Promoting Efficient Use of
Spectrum Through Elimination of Barriers to the Development of
Secondary Markets, Second Report and Order, Order on Reconsideration,
and Second Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 69 FR 77522, Dec. 27,
2004 (Secondary Markets Second Report and Order). The Commission
explained that it intended for its rules to allow more flexible use of
spectrum by licensees and other spectrum users, better define
licensees' and spectrum users' rights and responsibilities, enable the
use of spectrum across various dimensions (frequency, space, and time),
promote the efficient use of spectrum, and provide for continued
technological advances. While the Commission ostensibly extended the
new de facto control standard for spectrum manager leasing to DE
lessors, it nonetheless required that a licensee receiving DE
[[Page 68175]]
benefits be an entity that actually provides service under the license.
The Commission explained that it intended that DEs should remain
primarily providers of facilities-based service directly to the public.
That conclusion was based on an interpretation of the legislative
history underlying the Act's provisions regarding unjust enrichment, as
well as the continued application of the Commission's controlling
interest standard and affiliation rules.
14. In the Secondary Markets Second Report and Order, the
Commission also advised that in examining whether a spectrum lessee
would, under a spectrum manager lease, become a controlling interest or
affiliate of the licensee, the licensee should look to all of the
relevant circumstances, including how large a portion of its total
capacity to provide spectrum-based services would be leased, what
involvement it would have with the spectrum lessee as a result of the
spectrum lease, and what relationship the two parties have with one
another apart from the lease. The Commission concluded that a spectrum
manager lease between a designated entity licensee and a spectrum
lessee with a prior business relationship where substantially all of
the spectrum capacity of the licensee is to be leased would cause the
spectrum lessee to become an attributable affiliate of the licensee.
Such affiliation would render the licensee ineligible for designated
entity or entrepreneur benefits and, therefore, would make such a
spectrum lease impermissible. On the other hand, the Commission
reasoned that a spectrum manager lease involving a small portion of the
designated entity or entrepreneur licensee's spectrum capacity where no
relationship existed between the licensee and spectrum lessee apart
from the lease would likely be permissible. Situations falling
somewhere between these two examples would have to be evaluated
according to the individual circumstances involved.
15. Subsequently in 2006, at the behest of interested parties,
including Council Tree, the Commission released a further notice, which
sought comment on the specific nature of the types of relationships
that should trigger the attribution of revenues to determine
eligibility for designated entity benefits. See Implementation of the
Commercial Spectrum Enhancement Act and Modernization of the
Commission's Competitive Bidding Rules and Procedures, 71 FR 6992, Feb.
10, 2006. For instance, Council Tree initially proposed that the
Commission should restrict a designated entity applicant's ``material
relationships,'' including both financial and operational agreements,
in order to more carefully ensure that designated entity benefits are
awarded only to bona fide eligible entities. In the DE Second Report
and Order, the Commission, to further protect against unjust
enrichment, departed from its case-by-case approach and instead adopted
a bright-line test to require a small business applicant or licensee to
automatically attribute to itself the gross revenues of any entity with
which it had an ``attributable material relationship.'' It reasoned
that an agreement that concerns the actual use of the DE's spectrum
capacity is one that causes the relationship to be ripe for abuse and
creates the potential for the relationship to impede a DE's ability to
become a facilities-based provider, as intended by Congress. The
Commission concluded that an applicant or licensee has an AMR when it
has one or more agreements with any individual entity for the lease
(under either spectrum manager or de facto transfer leasing
arrangements) or resale (including under a wholesale arrangement) of,
on a cumulative basis, more than 25 percent of the spectrum capacity of
any individual license held by the applicant or licensee.
16. Council Tree and others challenged the AMR rule and other
aspects of the Commission's 2006 Order in the United States Court of
Appeals for the Third Circuit on the grounds that they failed to take
into account circumstances regarding small businesses' access to
capital, among other things. In subsequent years, the Office of
Advocacy in the U.S. Small Business Administration (SBA) also expressed
its belief to the Commission that the 2006 changes to the small
business rules had ``inhibited participation by small entities and
minority businesses in recent spectrum auctions,'' and that the changes
were unnecessary in light of the availability of the audit process
included in the Commission's original auction rules. In 2010, although
the court ultimately upheld the AMR rule, it nonetheless questioned
some of the Commission's reasoning, noting what it termed the
Commission's ``inattention'' to the nature of the wireless wholesale
business. Questioning why the Commission chose to attribute certain
relationships to achieve its stated policy of DEs as facilities-based
providers, the court observed that wholesaling includes an extensive
provision of service component. The court said that it was therefore
not obvious that the Commission needed to prohibit DEs from engaging
primarily in a wholesale business in order to prevent them from simply
monetizing their bidding credits with a large carrier, ``so long as
[DEs] do not sell or lease overly large quantities of their capacity to
any single lessee or buyer.'' Remarking that the Commission appeared
not to have acknowledged this issue, the court commended it to the
Commission's attention on remand.
17. Recently, in February 2014, the Minority Media & Telecom
Council (MMTC) filed a white paper with the Commission making nine
recommendations to facilitate the participation of minority- and women-
owned businesses in upcoming auctions. Listed first among these is the
repeal of the AMR rule. MMTC argues that the rule impedes the ability
of small entities to become providers of spectrum-based service,
explaining that wholesaling and leasing arrangements are important
vehicles for small and minority-owned businesses to build and
efficiently use capital.
18. MMTC's White Paper argues that ``over the course of fifty-six
wireless auctions during the past 20 years, the majority of DEs that
currently hold wireless licenses are incumbent rural telephone
companies, very few DEs are new entrants, and even fewer DEs are
(minority-owned business enterprises) MBEs.'' MMTC and its supporters
maintain that DE participation in spectrum auctions dramatically
decreased after the Commission's adoption of its 2006 rule
modifications and claim that the results from Auctions 66 and 73
``showed a precipitous drop in DE participation from the average 70%
value of winning bids over previous years, to only 4.0% and 2.6%
respectively.''
19. Other parties concur with MMTC's concerns about the AMR rule,
arguing that the development of the Commission's rules and policies
over the last decade, including adoption of the AMR rule, have
significantly hindered their ability to access capital and largely
impeded their ability to acquire and use wireless spectrum licenses in
today's wireless marketplace. Parties claim that the AMR rule creates
insurmountable obstacles for new and existing small businesses to gain
access to capital in secondary markets where they argue small
businesses can play important roles in assuring that licensed spectrum
is effectively and efficiently utilized. In a March 2014 request for
clarification or waiver of the AMR rule, Grain Management, LLC
described how the rule could prevent a small, minority-owned, new-
entrant lessor of spectrum capacity on licenses acquired without DE
benefits from being eligible for such benefits in future auctions. See
Grain Management, LLC's Request for
[[Page 68176]]
Clarification or Waiver of 47 CFR 1.2110(b)(3)(iv)(A); Implementation
of the Commercial Spectrum Enhancement Act and Modernization of the
Commission's Competitive Bidding Rules and Procedures; Expanding the
Economic and Innovation Opportunities of Spectrum Through Incentive
Auctions; Amendment of the Commission's Rules with Regard to Commercial
Operations in the 1695-1710 MHz, 1755-1780 MHz, and 2155-2180 MHz
Bands, WT Docket No. 05-211; GN Docket Nos. 12-268 and 13-185, Order,
29 FCC Rcd 9080 (2014).
20. Discussion. The Commission concludes that it is appropriate to
revisit its small business eligibility rules and evaluate whether to
rebalance its competing goals in order to provide small businesses
additional opportunities to gain access to new sources of capital
necessary for participation in the provision of spectrum-based services
in today's marketplace, while guarding against unjust enrichment of
ineligible entities. Chief among the actions that the Commission takes
in the Competitive Bidding NPRM is its proposal to repeal the AMR rule
and to re-examine the related decade-old policy underlying it. In lieu
of the bright-line test of the AMR rule, the Commission proposes a two-
pronged approach to evaluate an entity's eligibility for small business
benefits. This approach would use its existing controlling interest and
affiliation standards to determine what revenues are attributable to an
applicant based upon a rigorous review of all relevant relationships
and agreements, which will ensure that the small business makes
independent decisions about its business operation. Alternatively, the
Commission also seeks comment on whether it should retain the policy
but modify the AMR rule with some other attribution threshold to
determine an applicant's eligibility for small business benefits.
21. Using long standing principles of control and affiliation, the
Commission proposes to safeguard small business benefits by attributing
the revenues of any entity that has the ability to control, or
potentially control, an applicant's business venture. The Commission's
existing attribution rules examine the extent to which a small business
may combine its efforts, property, money, skill and knowledge with
another. Further, where there is an agreement to share profits/losses
proportionate to each party's contribution to the business operation,
the existing rules consider these issues as a factor in whether to
attribute that party to the applicant as its affiliate. Because the
Commission's proposals should allow small businesses greater
flexibility to engage in business ventures that include increased forms
of leasing and other spectrum use arrangements, the Commission
anticipates that the combined effect of the proposals--by allowing a
small business greater flexibility to adopt a more individualized
business model for each license it holds--should increase the potential
sources of revenue for the small business and potentially decrease the
likelihood that it would be subject to undue influence by any
particular user of a single license. The Commission's proposed approach
would also ensure that a licensee retains control of all licenses for
which it seeks bidding credits, while providing greater flexibility in
potential uses for any licenses acquired without such benefits. The
Commission seeks comment on this proposal and asks commenters to
specifically address how and why a small business may be more or less
likely to be subject to undue influence by a user of its spectrum under
this approach. Additionally, the Commission proposes to modify the
language of 47 CFR 1.9020 to make clear how the secondary market rules
apply to DE lessors, which should provide greater flexibility to small
businesses in how they choose to use their spectrum. The Commission
also seeks comment on whether any corresponding changes may be
warranted in its unjust enrichment rules to ensure that small business
bidding credits are extended only to qualifying small businesses.
22. The AMR rule and the policy that spurred its adoption were
intended to prevent unjust enrichment by establishing safeguards to
ensure that entities ineligible for small business incentives could not
circumvent the Commission's rules by obtaining those benefits
indirectly, through their relationships with eligible entities. The
Commission based its decisions, in large measure, on legislative
history suggesting that anti-trafficking restrictions and unjust
enrichment payment obligations were needed to deter participation in
the licensing process by those who have no intention of offering
service to the public. For example, in the Secondary Markets Second
Report and Order, the Commission relied on the legislative history in
rejecting a commenter's argument that ``[t]here [was] no reason to
believe that Congress intended to limit designated entities to only one
form of participation in the spectrum market--construction and
operation of a facilities-based network.'' In adopting the AMR rule,
the Commission reaffirmed that interpretation of the legislative
history, concluding that the adoption of the AMR rule, along with other
modifications, was necessary to strengthen its implementation of
Congress's directives with regard to DEs and to ensure that, in
accordance with the intent of Congress, every recipient of its DE
benefits is an entity that uses its licenses to directly provide
facilities-based telecommunications services for the benefit of the
public.
23. Yet, in the Commission's attempts to safeguard small business
benefits from unjust enrichment, it appears that the Commission's
policy and corresponding rule modifications may have had the unintended
consequence of hindering the Commission's ability to satisfy its
statutory goal of promoting opportunities for wireless entry by small
businesses. Moreover, the Commission notes that the statute does not
specifically state, nor does the House Report make clear, that Congress
intended to require that ``offering service to the public'' be defined
only as DEs directly providing facilities-based telecommunications
services for the benefit of the public. The Commission may have placed
undue weight on language from the House Report, given all of the
various factors that the actual text of 47 CFR 309(j) gives the
Commission the discretion to balance. In interpreting statutes,
analysis of the statutory text, aided by established principles of
interpretation, controls.
24. While the policy of requiring primarily the direct provision of
facilities-based service by a small business seeking bidding credits is
one way to protect against unjust enrichment, the Commission
tentatively concludes that it is not the only way to ensure that
benefits are provided solely to those entities that Congress intended.
The Commission also recognizes that the AMR rule, which was adopted to
further that policy, may inhibit the highest and best use of spectrum
by preventing small businesses that lack access to traditional sources
of capital from being able to acquire alternative revenue streams
through leasing and other spectrum use arrangements, even in
circumstances where they retain control over their business venture.
MMTC argues that there has been a documented decline in DE
participation and success at auction following the adoption of the
Commission's rule changes in 2006, based on the relative value of
licenses won by DEs compared to non-DEs. While the Commission notes
that the relative value of licenses won at auction is only one measure
to gauge success of the small business program and that there are other
[[Page 68177]]
relevant factors to consider in assessing whether the Commission has
met its statutory obligations for small businesses, the Commission
nonetheless concurs that over the last decade small businesses have
faced various increased difficulties in becoming wireless licensees.
25. The Commission contemplates that a different approach may be
more effective in balancing its competing goals of affording small
businesses reasonable flexibility to obtain the capital necessary to
participate in the provision of spectrum-based services and effectively
preventing the unjust enrichment of ineligible entities. Inasmuch as
Congress has granted the Commission the discretion to weigh the varying
objectives of section 309(j), the Commission proposes rule
modifications that, if adopted, could offer a more balanced approach
for achieving its statutory directives. The Commission therefore
proposes to repeal the AMR rule and evaluate small business eligibility
in a manner that could provide DEs with greater opportunities to
participate in the provision of spectrum-based services, including
through secondary market transactions. The Commission anticipates that
this, in turn, will help DEs gain access to capital by enabling leasing
and other spectrum use arrangements. Allowing more DEs and small
businesses to participate in spectrum leases and other spectrum use
agreements will also promote the Commission's goals of promoting more
efficient and dynamic use of the important spectrum resource through
secondary market spectrum transactions.
26. The Commission seeks comment on this proposal to repeal the AMR
rule, and its tentative conclusions regarding its need to re-evaluate
its small business policy. Should the Commission discontinue its policy
requiring small businesses seeking bidding credits to provide primarily
direct, facilities-based service on each individual license? Would this
proposal better promote Congress's intent for small businesses? Would
the proposal to eliminate this policy and to repeal the AMR rule have
the unintended effect of providing ineligible entities with access to
discounted spectrum?
27. In a mature wireless industry where leasing and other spectrum
use arrangements may be important tools to enable wireless providers to
raise capital and participate at auction, is it appropriate to provide
small businesses seeking bidding credits with greater flexibility to
enter into such spectrum use arrangements? Should the Commission
consider an alternative spectrum capacity use limit for a bright-line
attribution test, and if so what is the appropriate percentage and what
spectrum use arrangements should it include? Would eliminating the
policy that small businesses provide primarily facilities-based service
with each individual license increase or decrease the risk of unjust
enrichment to ineligible entities and/or the warehousing of spectrum?
What safeguards should the Commission consider to ensure that bidding
credits are extended only to qualifying small businesses, as Congress
intended? Alternatively, should the Commission retain the AMR rule and
the related policy that small businesses primarily provide facilities-
based service, but stipulate that neither would kick in for a set
number of years? This approach might provide small businesses with an
opportunity to raise capital early in the license term but still
require that they eventually become primarily facilities-based
providers of service when the AMR rule kicks in. Commenters should
address when the AMR rule and the related policy regarding facilities-
based service should kick in and how construction build-out
requirements should be measured. Commenters should also address whether
the Commission's proposed shift in policy would continue to allow
auctions to award licenses to those entities that value the spectrum
most highly, which fosters the Commission's ability to accomplish
Congress's multi-faceted policy objectives. Will rebalancing the
Commission's approach to Congress's goals provide adequate safeguards
against unjust enrichment to ensure that bidding credits are awarded
only to qualifying small businesses?
28. Proposed Standard for Evaluating Small Business Eligibility.
The Commission proposes a more focused approach to evaluate small
business eligibility that looks at who controls, or has the potential
to control, the applicant and any spectrum acquired with the use of
small business benefits. Specifically, the Commission proposes to apply
a two-pronged test using its existing controlling interest and
affiliation rules to determine: (1) Whether an applicant meets the
applicable small business size standard, and (2) whether it retains
control over the spectrum associated with the licenses for which it
seeks small business benefits. This approach will allow the Commission
to separate its review of those who control, or have the power to
control, the small business applicant's business venture, and are
therefore attributable for purposes of determining eligibility, from
those that use (and may control) its spectrum capacity, which would
affect the small business's ability to retain its benefits with respect
to any particular license. Consistent with the Commission's existing
controlling interest and affiliation rules under 47 CFR
1.2110(c)(2)(ii)(H)-(I), it will attribute the revenues of those
entities or individuals that determine or significantly influence the
nature or types of services offered by the small business, the terms
upon which such services are offered, and the prices charged for such
services. The Commission's proposals would expand the types of services
the small business might offer as part of its overall business venture,
but would not alter how the Commission carefully monitors those that
have the ability to control, or potentially control, the applicant or
licensee and its business venture. The Commission seeks comment on
these specific proposals.
29. The first prong would evaluate whether an applicant meets the
applicable small business size standard and is therefore eligible for
benefits. To evaluate small business eligibility, the Commission
proposes to apply its existing controlling interest standard and
affiliation rules to determine whether an entity should be attributable
based on whether that entity has de jure or de facto control of, or is
affiliated with, the applicant's overall business venture. De jure
control is typically evidenced by the holding of greater than 50
percent of the voting stock of a corporation or, in the case of a
partnership, general partnership interests. De facto control is
determined on a case-by-case basis to determine whether the licensee
has actual control over its business venture. Thus, pursuant to 47 CFR
1.2110 and consistent with the Commission's current analysis, under its
proposal, control and affiliation may arise through, among other
things, ownership interests, voting interests, or the terms of any
agreements that create a controlling, or potentially controlling,
relationship over the applicant's business venture. The Commission
therefore notes that its proposal to eliminate the policy that small
businesses seeking benefits primarily provide facilities-based service
does not alter the rules that require it to consider whether
facilities-sharing and other agreements confer control of or create
affiliation with the applicant. The proposal also does not alter the
general standard by which the Commission
[[Page 68178]]
evaluates whether a licensee has ceded de facto control and effected an
unauthorized transfer of control of its spectrum authorization to a
third party.
30. The Commission's continued careful and targeted examination of
these issues will allow it to ensure that a small business applicant
has the independent ability to direct its decision making regarding its
overall business venture and how its licenses are used to offer service
to the public. Moreover, those claiming small business benefits will
continue to be bound by the Commission's existing rules regarding
control and attribution, which should be familiar to all existing and
future Commission licensees. By providing small businesses with greater
opportunities to access revenue streams through leasing and other
spectrum use agreements, the Commission anticipates that they will have
more flexibility to employ business models that suit their individual
needs and therefore will be less likely to be influenced by deep-
pocketed investors or parties with which they have a spectrum use
agreement. Furthermore, this approach recognizes the Commission's
earlier conclusion in the Secondary Markets proceeding that the mere
existence of a spectrum use agreement between a small business and
another party does not, without more, cause the other party to become
an attributable interest holder in the applicant. This approach,
coupled with the Commission's proposed departure from the policy of
requiring small businesses to provide primarily facilities-based
service directly to the public with each of its licenses, should allow
small businesses to gain access to capital and better enable them to
participate in auctions and in the provision of spectrum-based
services, so long as the terms of any spectrum use agreement do not
confer control or create an affiliation that would lead to attribution
of disqualifying revenues. Will this approach promote long-term
investment, market participation and competition in the wireless
industry by small businesses?
31. Once the first prong has been met, the Commission would
evaluate eligibility under the second prong. Under the second prong,
the Commission proposes to determine an entity's eligibility to retain
small business benefits on a license-by-license basis, based on whether
the entity has maintained de jure and de facto control of the license.
Under this proposed license-by-license approach, an entity will not
necessarily lose its eligibility for all current and future small
business benefits solely because of a decision associated with any
particular license. Instead, while a small business might incur unjust
enrichment obligations if it relinquishes de jure or de facto control
of any particular license for which it claimed benefits, so long as the
revenues of its attributable interest holders (i.e., the DE's
affiliates, its controlling interests, and the affiliates of its
controlling interests) continue to qualify under the relevant small
business size standard, it could still retain its eligibility to retain
current and future benefits on existing and future licenses. In other
words, an applicant need not be eligible for small business benefits on
each of the licenses it holds in order to demonstrate its overall
eligibility for such benefits. For instance, if a small business
chooses to permissibly relinquish benefits, incurring any applicable
unjust enrichment obligation, and transfer de facto control of a
license through a de facto transfer lease, that lease will not
necessarily make the lessee an attributable interest holder in the
applicant or cause the applicant to become ineligible for other small
business benefits it might have or want to acquire.
32. The Commission stresses that small businesses, like all its
licensees, remain subject to its rules to prevent unauthorized
transfers of control of their license authorizations pursuant to
section 310(d) of the Act. Accordingly, if a small business seeking
benefits executes a spectrum use agreement that does not comply with
the Commission's relevant standard of de facto control, it will be
subject to unjust enrichment obligations for the benefits associated
with that particular license. If the terms of that spectrum use
agreement go so far as to confer control of, or the potential to
control, the small business's overall business venture, the business
could risk the attribution of revenues, which could render it
ineligible for all current and future small business benefits on all
licenses. Except where the leasing standard of de facto control applies
under the secondary market rules, the criteria of Intermountain
Microwave and Ellis Thompson will continue to apply to any Commission
licensee, including a small business, for purposes of assessing whether
it can demonstrate that it retains de facto control of its business
venture and spectrum authorization. See Applications for Microwave
Transfers to Teleprompter Approved with Warning; Non-broadcast and
General Action Report No. 1142, Public Notice (by the Commission en
banc), 12 FCC 2d 559, 559-60 (1963) (Intermountain Microwave); Ellis
Thompson Corporation, 60 FR 1776, Jan. 5, 1995. Small businesses will,
however, be free under this proposal from the added policy requirement
regarding the extent to which it must use each individual spectrum
license for the provision of facilities-based service in order to
retain eligibility for small business benefits.
33. The Commission seeks comment on its proposed two-pronged
approach to evaluate attribution and establish eligibility for small
business benefits. Will this proposal provide small businesses with the
flexibility necessary to participate in an evolving wireless
marketplace? Does the absence of a bright-line attribution standard
hinder an applicant's ability to assess its eligibility for small
business benefits? Will the Commission's proposed approach allow it to
safeguard the benefits it awards and prevent ineligible entities from
obtaining benefits indirectly, through arrangements with eligible small
businesses? Should the Commission take additional steps to assure that
ineligible entities cannot exercise undue influence over a small
business, or will its proposed approach empower small businesses to
make their own decisions with respect to the highest and best use of
each of their licenses without risking the undue influence of their
investors or spectrum users? For instance, should the Commission, in
considering whether the user's revenues should be attributable to the
small business applicant, consider any limits on the amount of its
spectrum capacity a small business seeking benefits can allow a third
party to use, even where such use is otherwise permissible under
Commission rules and the agreement on its own does not create a
controlling interest or affiliation in the applicant's business
venture?
34. Should the Commission limit the ability of a small business
seeking benefits to lease all of its spectrum capacity or should the
Commission allow it to be primarily engaged in the business of leasing
provided that it complies with small business eligibility rules? Would
allowing a small business seeking benefits to lease 100 percent of its
spectrum capacity on any individual license, and/or on all of its
licenses, increase the potential of the unjust enrichment of ineligible
entities? Commenters should address how that risk increases or
decreases based on the amount of spectrum capacity that may be leased.
Should the Commission be concerned that a small business leasing large
quantities of its spectrum capacity to a single user has allowed
another entity to receive the benefit of its bidding credits?
[[Page 68179]]
35. Should there be a standard by which the Commission should
automatically attribute the gross revenues of an entity with which a
small business seeking benefits has spectrum use agreements if it has
such agreements with a single entity in numerous markets? How should
the Commission view small businesses that have multiple financial and/
or operational arrangements with another licensee or entity where the
agreements do not otherwise create a controlling interest or
affiliation with the small business? Should the existence of such
multiple agreements create a rebuttable presumption of affiliation
similar to the kinship affiliation rule, or does the Commission's
existing rule of ``affiliation through contractual relationships''
already adequately guard against a third party acquiring control, or
the potential to control, the small business through such agreements?
For instance, should the Commission permit a small business seeking
benefits to have a combination of capital investments, loan, marketing,
management and leasing agreements with another Commission licensee
without attributing the gross revenues of that entity to the small
business? Is there a combination of agreements that should cause more
concern in assessing small business benefit eligibility, and should any
combination of agreements with a single party create a rebuttable
presumption of attribution or an ineligibility for small business
benefits? Are there any specific types of agreements that are more
likely to confer control or undue influence of the small business
seeking benefits that should cause the Commission to automatically
attribute the gross revenues of the entity to the small business or
render the small business ineligible for benefits?
36. Do the Commission's proposals provide small business applicants
with sufficient flexibility to access capital, compete in auctions, and
participate in new and innovative ways in the provision of service in
the wireless marketplace while retaining their benefits? Do the
Commission's proposals make it more or less likely that a small
business will be unduly influenced by the entities with which it
engages in spectrum use agreements? Commenters opposing these proposals
should indicate specific concerns. Commenters supporting these
proposals should offer any other suggestions the Commission should
consider to revise its rules and reform its small business policies. To
what extent do the Commission's proposed changes for small business
eligibility positively or negatively affect auction revenues? To what
extent do the Commission's proposals appropriately balance its
competing statutory obligations in section 309(j) of the Act?
37. Proposed Standard for Evaluating DE Leasing. The Commission
also proposes to modify the language of 47 CFR 1.9020 to comport with
the Commission's proposed approach to assessing small business
eligibility. Specifically, the Commission proposes to make clear that
DEs may fully benefit from the same de facto control standard for
spectrum manager leasing in the Commission's secondary market rules as
non-DE lessors.
38. In developing its regulatory scheme for leasing generally, the
Commission determined that section 310(d) of the Act did not require
the continued application of the facilities-based Intermountain
Microwave six-part test that had, since 1963, been applied to determine
whether a licensee was exercising the requisite level of de facto
control over its licensed operations. Instead, the Commission adopted a
revised de facto control standard for leasing arrangements for purposes
of applying the requirements of section 310(d). Under the revised
standard, a spectrum manager lease does not constitute a transfer of de
facto control so long as the licensee (1) maintains an active, ongoing
oversight role in ensuring that the lessee complies with Commission
rules and policies; (2) retains responsibility for all interactions
with the Commission required under the license related to the use of
the leased spectrum; and (3) remains primarily and directly accountable
to the Commission for any lessee violation of these policies and rules.
39. While the Commission nominally applied the new standard to all
licensees, it explained that DEs would be required to retain their
eligibility under the traditional facilities-focused de facto control
standard of 47 CFR 1.2110 and Intermountain Microwave. Thus, the
Commission stated that small businesses could engage in leasing only to
the extent that doing so would not affect their eligibility for
benefits. Further, it required that a licensee receiving DE benefits be
an entity that actually provides service under the license. As
explained above, the Commission expressed concern that unless it
continued to require DEs to remain engaged primarily in the provision
of facilities-based services to the public it would run the risk that
small business incentives, particularly bidding credits, would
indirectly benefit entities that would not qualify for those incentives
in the primary market. To that end, the Commission specified that small
businesses could not retain their benefits if they made spectrum
leasing their primary business.
40. Consistent with the Commission's proposed revisions to
assessing small business eligibility, including the elimination of the
requirement that small businesses primarily provide facilities-based
service on each license they hold, the Commission proposes a
modification to its spectrum manager leasing rule. Specifically, the
Commission proposes to modify the language in 47 CFR 1.9020(d)(4) to
remove the conflicting reference to the control standard of 47 CFR
1.2110 in order to make clear that small business lessors are fully
subject to the same de facto control standard for spectrum manager
leasing that applies to all other licensees. This modification should
clarify that 47 CFR 1.9010 alone defines whether a licensee, including
a small business, retains de facto control of the spectrum that it
leases to a spectrum lessee in the context of spectrum manager leasing.
This proposal does not alter the fact that small businesses must remain
eligible for benefits under 47 CFR 1.2110. Instead, the proposed
modification clarifies that one de facto standard applies to determine
whether the licensee has de facto control of the spectrum in the
context of a spectrum manager lease (i.e., 47 CFR 1.9010), and the
other applies to determine whether a third party has control, or the
potential to control, the licensee and its business venture for the
purposes of attribution of revenues (i.e., 47 CFR 1.2110). In sum, the
Commission's proposal departs from the traditional Intermountain
Microwave facilities-focused de facto control standard with regard to
an individual spectrum lease agreement for a particular license. As
long as the small business: (1) Maintains an active, ongoing oversight
role in ensuring that the lessee complies with Commission rules and
policies; (2) retains responsibility for all interactions with the
Commission required under the license related to the use of the leased
spectrum; and (3) remains primarily and directly accountable to the
Commission for any lessee violation of these policies and rules, it
will be considered to maintain de facto control of its spectrum for the
purposes of that spectrum manager lease. Spectrum manager leasing
applications will continue to be evaluated to determine whether control
of, or affiliation with, the small business applicant and its overall
business venture has arisen through any the terms of the leasing
[[Page 68180]]
agreement that might lead to attribution and result in unjust
enrichment under 47 CFR 1.2110.
41. When the Commission adopted 47 CFR 1.9010, it noted that a
licensee's continued control over the licensed use of spectrum lies at
the heart of what it means to retain the license and the rights
thereunder and that it could no longer generally assume that the
licensee must perform the non-licensed activities identified in
Intermountain Microwave in order to conclude that the licensee has
retained its license and all rights thereunder. The Commission proposes
that its modification will make clear that this conclusion applies
equally to all licensees. Are there any reasons why the Commission
should retain its existing language in 47 CFR 1.9020(d)(4)? Should the
Commission consider limiting the amount of spectrum a small business
can lease to a single entity under 47 CFR 1.9020, in order to ensure
that the small business retains control over its business venture as
required in 47 CFR 1.2110? Commenters opposing the Commission's
proposal should offer alternative suggestions for how it could allow
small businesses to play a larger role in secondary market
transactions.
B. Unjust Enrichment
42. The integrity of the small business benefit program depends on
ensuring that only entities eligible for benefits receive them. To
safeguard against abuse, the Commission has long relied on unjust
enrichment provisions, which require a small business to pay back the
benefits it accrued where appropriate, and careful vigilance in
approving applications and transactions. With the proposals set forth
in the Competitive Bidding NPRM, the Commission anticipates that these
provisions will be as important as ever and that strong enforcement of
the provisions is critical. The Commission therefore seeks comment on
whether any changes are appropriate to strengthen its unjust enrichment
rules and how best the Commission can continue to scrutinize
applications and proposed transactions to ensure that only eligible
entities receive benefits, while not undermining the Act's directive to
ensure that DEs are given the opportunity to participate in the
provision of spectrum-based services.
43. Pursuant to 47 CFR 1.2111(b), small businesses are obligated to
make unjust enrichment payments if they seek, inter alia, to assign or
transfer control of licenses to a non-eligible party, for a period of
up to five years from the initial issuance of the license. In
rebalancing the Commission's policy objectives to provide small
businesses greater opportunities to participate at auction and in the
provision of spectrum-based services, it remains focused on its
responsibility to ensure that benefits are provided only to qualifying
entities.
44. The Commission therefore invites comment on whether its
existing five year unjust enrichment payment schedule continues to
provide a sufficient safeguard to ensure that benefits are provided
only to qualifying entities. Commenters should be specific about
whether there is a need to adjust its current five year unjust
enrichment repayment schedule, and the appropriate length and
reimbursement percentages for any repayment schedule revisions. If
commenters support a different repayment period or different
percentages for the repayment schedule, they should be specific about
why their suggested approach would better meet its goals and balance
the Commission's statutory objectives.
45. Specifically, the Commission also seeks comment on whether it
should consider adopting a 10 year unjust enrichment repayment schedule
for licenses acquired with bidding credits, including its benefits and
costs. Extending the length of the unjust enrichment repayment schedule
to 10 years may help deter speculation and prevent spectrum
warehousing. At the same time, extending the length of the unjust
enrichment repayment schedule could restrict small businesses' access
to capital, which could limit their ability to participate in the
provision of spectrum-based services, contrary to the Commission's
underlying goals in this proceeding. How does the length of the
repayment schedule affect a small business's capital fundraising and
business planning efforts? Are there lessons the Commission can draw
from based on parties' experience raising capital when the 10 year
unjust enrichment period was in place from 2006 until 2010? If the
Commission repeals the AMR rule as proposed and also modifies the
unjust enrichment rules, what would be the combined effect on the
ability of a small business to raise capital and participate at auction
and in the provision of service, particularly when compared to the
existing rule?
46. Are there other unjust enrichment provisions that the
Commission should consider? For example, should the Commission require
full reimbursement, plus interest, if a small business loses its
eligibility prior to meeting the construction requirements applicable
at the end of the license term? Commenters should discuss how such an
approach would impact the Commission's interest in protecting against
unjust enrichment, while ensuring that small businesses have access to
capital to participate at auction and in the provision of service. Is a
different reimbursement percentage (something less than 100 percent)
preferable? Are other safeguards sufficient to protect the Commission's
interests regarding unjust enrichment?
47. The Commission seeks comment on whether it may grant small
businesses greater flexibility to participate in the provision of
spectrum-based services, as it has proposed, while also ensuring that
only those entities Congress intended have access to benefits. The
Commission asks commenters to address how the unjust enrichment rules
affect their ability to secure and retain capital and whether its rules
require other further modifications to safeguard the award of small
business benefits. By granting small businesses greater regulatory
flexibility to demonstrate eligibility, does the Commission increase or
decrease the likelihood that non-eligible entities can assert undue
influence over a small business's decision making for its business
venture and its utilization of licenses to participate in the provision
of spectrum-based services?
48. The Commission also seeks comment on how other government
programs ensure that only an intended class of recipients receive
benefits that are awarded to eligible entities. Are there other
government programs that have greater safeguards than the Commission
currently employs? How do other government agencies and small business
benefit programs prevent abuse and guard against unjust enrichment of
ineligible entities? Commenters should be specific about any analogies
that can be drawn between the Commission's small business benefits and
similar benefits awarded by other agencies and programs.
49. The Commission's efforts to provide increased flexibility to
small businesses must be balanced with vigilant enforcement to ensure
that only bona fide small businesses receive benefits. The Commission
has a strong interest in ensuring that truthful and accurate
information is available to the Commission and the public for purposes
of implementing and enforcing policies it finds to be in the public
interest. Such information is imperative to the Commission's ability to
safeguard the benefits it awards and to prevent unjust enrichment. To
the extent the Commission modifies rules regarding its small business
benefits, it will remain vigilant in undertaking careful review of
[[Page 68181]]
all applications of those seeking to acquire or retain bidding credits
to ensure that the gross revenues of all parties that control, or have
the potential to control, the applicant are properly attributed in
compliance with its controlling interest and affiliation rules. The
Commission emphasizes that it will remain focused on ensuring that an
applicant's certifications for eligibility comport with the actual
terms of its agreements with relevant parties. In so doing, the
Commission expects that it can properly execute its statutory
responsibility to continue to prevent unjust enrichment of ineligible
entities.
C. Bidding Credits
50. The Commission also takes a fresh look at the primary way that
it facilitates participation by small businesses at auction through its
bidding credit program. The Commission notes that the generally
applicable small business definitions and corresponding bidding
preferences were adopted in 1997 and finds that it is appropriate to
revisit whether these standards have kept pace with an evolving
wireless marketplace. Toward that end, the Commission proposes to
increase the general size standards, measured by gross revenues, for
purposes of determining an entity's eligibility for a bidding
preference. The Commission also proposes to continue its practice of
evaluating which small business definitions will apply on a service-by-
service basis, based upon associated capital requirements for a
particular service. In addition, the Commission seeks comment on
whether to increase the bidding credit percentages applicable to
associated small business categories. Finally, the Commission seeks
comment on its ability to consider bidding preferences for other types
of DEs, entities that serve unserved/underserved areas or areas with
persistent poverty, as well as persons and entities that have overcome
disadvantages. The Commission expects that the questions raised here
will provide a meaningful opportunity to evaluate whether its bidding
credit program continues to achieve its objectives. The Commission
seeks concrete, specific, data-driven feedback by commenters to
facilitate its review. The Commission invites commenters to suggest
other creative ideas that would promote its statutory objectives, but
it emphasizes that for any such proposals it is imperative to provide
ample supporting evidence.
51. An auction applicant may claim eligibility for a bidding credit
when filing a short-form application. The Commission's short-form
application is the first part of its two-phased auction application
process. In the first phase, any party desiring to participate in an
auction must file a streamlined short-form application in which it
certifies under penalty of perjury as to its qualifications to
participate in a Commission auction. In its review of the short-form
applications, Commission staff presume the information and
certifications contained in the short-form applications are true unless
they are incomplete, internally inconsistent or contradicted by
information in the Commission's records. Eligibility to participate in
bidding is based on information in an applicant's short-form
application and its certifications, and on its upfront payment. In the
second phase of the Commission's application process, a winning bidder
files a more comprehensive long-form (FCC Form 601) application. The
long-form application is subject to more extensive review and is the
basis for any determination that a winning bidder is qualified to hold
a Commission license and for the award of any claimed bidding credit.
1. Small Business Bidding Credits
52. Background. Bidding credits operate as a percentage discount on
the winning bid amounts of a qualifying small business. By making the
acquisition of spectrum licenses more affordable for new and existing
small businesses, bidding credits facilitate their access to needed
capital. The Commission establishes eligibility for bidding credits for
each auctionable service, adopting one or more definitions of the small
businesses that will be eligible. The Commission's small business
definitions have been based on an applicant's average annual gross
revenues over a three-year period. In establishing the gross revenues
thresholds for the small business definitions to be applied to a
specific service, the Commission takes into account the capital
requirements and other characteristics of the particular service. In
order to qualify for a small business bidding credit an applicant must
demonstrate that its gross revenues, in combination with those of its
``attributable'' interest holders, fall below the applicable financial
caps.
53. The Commission's rules provide a schedule of small business
definitions and corresponding bidding credits. In adopting bidding
credits for a particular service, the Commission has found that the use
of the small business size standards and credits set forth in the part
1 schedule provides consistency and predictability for small
businesses. Section 1.2110(f) sets forth three tiers of bidding
credits: (1) A 35 percent bidding credit for businesses with average
annual gross revenues for the preceding three years not exceeding $3
million; (2) A 25 percent bidding credit for businesses with average
annual gross revenues for the preceding three years not exceeding $15
million; and (3) A 15 percent bidding credit for businesses with
average annual gross revenues for the preceding three years not
exceeding $40 million.
54. Discussion. The Commission proposes to increase the gross
revenues thresholds defining the three tiers of small businesses in the
part 1 schedule by which the Commission provides the corresponding
available bidding credits and seeks comment on alternatives. The
Commission also proposes to continue its practice of deciding which
small business definitions will apply on a service-by-service basis
depending on the capital requirements of the particular spectrum to be
auctioned. In addition, the Commission seeks comment on whether the
bidding credit percentages that apply to these small business
definitions should be increased.
55. Since the inception of the Commission's DE program, and
particularly in the past decade, the evolution of the mobile wireless
marketplace from mobile voice to mobile broadband has increased the
demands on wireless networks and the need for access to spectrum,
heightening the capital-intensive nature of the industry. Moreover, the
number of small and regional mobile wireless service providers has
significantly decreased, though regional and local service providers
continue to offer consumers additional choices in the areas they serve.
In light of these changes and statutory goals, the Commission seeks
comment on how it should reconsider definitions of what constitutes a
small business in the wireless industry.
56. The Commission proposes to increase the gross revenues
thresholds in its part 1 schedule to reflect the changing nature of the
wireless industry, including the overall increase in the size of
wireless networks and the increase in capital costs to deploy them. The
Commission notes that these changes have resulted in an increase in the
size of the wireless service providers that can be considered to be
``small'' relative to the large nationwide providers. By proposing
adjustments to the Commission's small business size standards, it aims
to promote the effective participation of small businesses in auctions
and in the provision of spectrum-based services.
57. In considering how much to adjust the gross revenues
thresholds, the
[[Page 68182]]
Commission proposes to use the price index for the U.S. Gross Domestic
Product (GDP price index) published by the U.S. Department of Commerce
(Commerce). The Commission notes that the SBA, as part of its size
standards review, recently used the GDP price index to adjust its
receipts-based industry size standards. In particular, the Commission
proposes to adjust the current gross revenues thresholds with the
percentage change in the GDP price index between 1997 and 2013. The
indices are available on Commerce's Bureau of Economic Analysis Web
site, under Tables 1.1.4 and 1.1.15, at https://www.bea.gov/itable.
58. The Commission believes that the GDP price index may reflect
certain industry trends and a relevant range of economic activity
better than the available wireless industry price indices published by
the Bureau of Labor and Statistics (BLS). In barely a decade, the shift
from a voice-centric to a data-centric wireless industry has seen
mobile broadband data services grow from their nascent stage to become
a significant share of the industry's market revenues. However, the
available wireless industry price indices may under represent broadband
data services because the indices are based on voice-centric
definitions of service plans. Moreover, broadband data plans are not
treated as a separate category in the indices, and the BLS description
of the indices is unclear about how the advent of mobile broadband
services has been factored into the voice-centric consumer and producer
prices indices that were introduced in 1997 and 1999, respectively.
Furthermore, the wireless industry consumer and producer price indices
may exclude goods and inputs that are relevant for the range of
economic activity involved in the provision of wireless services.
Therefore, the Commission proposes to use the broader GDP price index.
The GDP price index increased by 36.4 percent from 1997 to 2013. Based
on this 36.4 percent increase, the Commission proposes new gross
revenues thresholds that are obtained by multiplying the current
thresholds by 1.364 and rounding to the nearest million. Specifically,
the Commission proposes to revise the standardized schedule in 47 CFR
1.2110(f) as follows: (1) Businesses with average annual gross revenues
for the preceding three years not exceeding $4 million would be
eligible for a 35 percent bidding credit; (2) Businesses with average
annual gross revenues for the preceding three years not exceeding $20
million would be eligible for a 25 percent bidding credit; and (3)
Businesses with average annual gross revenues for the preceding three
years not exceeding $55 million would be eligible for a 15 percent
bidding credit.
59. The Commission seeks comment on its proposal to adjust the
current gross revenues thresholds in its small business size standards
using the GDP price index. Is there a different price index that better
reflects industry developments and the relevant range of economic
activity? Is there an alternative method for setting new gross revenues
thresholds that does not require adjusting the current gross revenues
thresholds with a price index?
60. The Commission tentatively concludes that its proposed gross
revenues thresholds better reflect the larger size of wireless networks
today, and thus expect that they will preserve the effectiveness of the
Commission's bidding credit program in the current mobile wireless
marketplace. Consumer demand for widely available mobile broadband
services has increased providers' need for additional capital to
acquire spectrum and deploy service. This trend is reflected in the
changing structure of the industry. By increasing the gross revenues
thresholds that define small businesses and thereby making bidding
credits available to a larger number of entities, the Commission seeks
to facilitate a higher rate of participation by entities that might
otherwise find it difficult to obtain the necessary capital to
participate at auction. The Commission seeks comment on whether the
proposed increases in the revenues thresholds are likely to increase
the percentage of entities that will benefit from its small business
bidding credits, by providing better access to capital and enabling
them to seek access to the spectrum necessary to meet consumer demand
for mobile broadband services. At the same time, to further the
statutory objectives of the auction program, the Commission must adopt
revenues thresholds that will avoid including firms that have adequate
access to financing for spectrum based on their revenue levels. The
Commission therefore seeks to avoid setting eligibility for bidding
credits at a level that is over inclusive, which would defeat the
purpose of the bidding credits and undermine the statutory objectives
of the program. Any new thresholds the Commission adopts should provide
economic opportunity to small businesses, while maintaining good
economic incentives for small businesses to seek diverse forms of
financing for spectrum.
61. The Commission seeks comment on this proposal. Specifically,
how have capital costs, construction costs, and administrative costs
faced by wireless providers changed since the mid-1990s? Have the costs
of spectrum usage rights increased significantly since the early stages
of the Commission's auction program such that it is more difficult for
small businesses to acquire wireless spectrum today?
62. Commenters who agree that the industry's evolution warrants new
definitions for small businesses should discuss what gross revenues
thresholds are appropriate for defining small businesses in the
wireless context. Commenters should explain their methodologies for
deriving alternative thresholds and should supply supporting data or
justifications for the Commission's use in evaluating and applying such
methodologies. If commenters do not provide data on wireless providers'
gross revenues, what alternative factors should the Commission consider
in determining what constitutes a ``small business'' in today's
wireless marketplace?
63. The Commission also seeks comment on whether to adopt a small
business size standard based on criteria other than gross revenues. As
the Commission recently noted in the AWS-3 proceeding, in first
adopting gross revenues-based small business size standards for
eligibility for DE benefits, the Commission rejected the SBA's
employee-based business size standard for cellular or other wireless
telecommunications entities as a means to qualify as a DE. The
Commission concluded that such a definition would be too inclusive and
would allow many large telecommunications firms to take advantage of
preferences not intended for them. The Commission notes that according
to census data, if it adopted the SBA's small business employee-based
size standard for cellular or other wireless telecommunications
entities (i.e., 1,500 or fewer employees) more than 96 percent of
wireless companies would be considered small businesses. The Commission
therefore tentatively concludes not to reconsider its conclusion that
the SBA's employee-based definition is too inclusive for the purposes
of establishing DE eligibility.
64. In addition, the Commission asks commenters to consider whether
it should increase the bidding credit percentages (i.e., discount
amounts) currently available to small businesses in 47 CFR 1.2110(f).
Should the Commission use the existing bidding credit percentages, but
apply them to higher gross revenues thresholds? Should the Commission
add additional
[[Page 68183]]
small business definitions and associated tiers of bidding credits
above or below the tiers proposed above? Commenters supporting
additional tiers of bidding credits should propose a corresponding
gross revenues threshold for each additional tier. Commenters
supporting changes to the existing bidding credit percentages in the
Commission's part 1 rules should explain the basis for their proposals
and provide any supporting data for the Commission's use in evaluating
potential changes to the part 1 schedule. Commenters should also
address whether increases in the bidding credit percentages are
necessary if the Commission adopts its proposal to modify the gross
revenues thresholds for its small business definitions since that will
have the effect of increasing the level of bidding credit a substantial
number of small businesses would receive compared to its current rules.
For instance, by increasing the revenues thresholds, entities
previously eligible for small business bidding credits under the
current schedule may become eligible for a higher bidding credit tier
under the proposed amended schedule, and entities that previously
exceeded the highest revenue threshold may become eligible. Similarly,
bidders that previously exceeded the thresholds as a result of
attributable revenues under the AMR rule may fall below the thresholds,
and thus become eligible for small business bidding credits, if the AMR
rule is eliminated as proposed in the Competitive Bidding NPRM.
65. Further, the Commission proposes to continue its practice of
soliciting comment on the appropriate small business size standards in
connection with establishing rules for any particular service. As the
Commission has done in the past and pursuant to 47 CFR 1.2110(c)(1), it
would continue to take into consideration the characteristics and
capital requirements of each service. The Commission seeks comment on
this proposal. Alternatively, should the Commission utilize all three
small business definitions and bidding credit tiers in every service?
Under this approach, the Commission would make bidding credits
available to any business that meets one of the small business
definitions without engaging in an assessment of the likely capital
requirements of the specific service for which licenses are being
offered. What are the advantages and disadvantages of this alternative
approach? If the Commission continues to adopt small business
definitions on a service-by-service basis, are there other factors that
it should consider in determining which small business definition to
apply to a specific service? Alternatively, if the Commission adopts
its proposed modifications to the AMR and small business size
standards, should it consider reducing the level of bidding credits it
awards? Commenters should provide specific suggestions on how the
Commission should weigh its proposals collectively.
66. The Commission also seeks comment on whether any revisions it
adopts in this proceeding to its part 1 schedule of small business size
standards and associated bidding credit percentage levels should apply
to the specific small business definitions and bidding credit
percentages the Commission has previously adopted for specific
services, and, if so, how such revisions would be implemented. In
particular, the Commission proposes that any new rules adopted in this
proceeding would apply to the 600 MHz band spectrum licenses to be
offered in the BIA. In the BIA proceeding, the Commission adopted a 15
percent bidding credit for small businesses (defined as entities with
average annual gross revenues for the preceding three years not
exceeding $40 million) and a 25 percent bidding credit for very small
businesses (defined as entities with average annual gross revenues for
the preceding three years not exceeding $15 million). Consistent with
the increased gross revenues thresholds the Commission proposes for the
standardized schedule in its part 1 competitive bidding rules, the
Commission also proposes to increase the gross revenues thresholds
associated with the 15 and 25 percent bidding credits adopted for the
600 MHz band. That is, for the 600 MHz band, the Commission proposes to
provide a bidding credit of 25 percent for businesses with average
gross revenues for the preceding three years not exceeding $20 million
and a bidding credit of 15 percent for businesses with average gross
revenues for the preceding three years not exceeding $55 million. The
Commission seeks comment on this proposal. In addition, the Commission
seeks comment on whether to adopt a third tier of small business
bidding credits for the 600 MHz band that would provide a 35 percent
bidding credit to businesses with average gross revenues for the
preceding three years not exceeding $4 million. If the Commission re-
auctions licenses for existing services, should the previously adopted
service-specific small business definitions and bidding credit
percentages be revised for those services to reflect any changes to its
part 1 schedule in 47 CFR 1.2110(f)(2)?
2. Other Bidding Preferences
67. The Commission's primary method of fulfilling its statutory
mandate regarding DEs has been to offer auction bidding credits to
small business applicants. Periodically, however, interested parties
have suggested that the Commission offer bidding preferences to
entities based on criteria other than business size. As the Commission
has explained in the past, its ability to implement suggestions to
target bidding credits to other types of entities is constrained by
both its statutory authority and standards of judicial review. The
Commission seeks comment on these suggestions and asks commenters to
specifically address the statutory authority and judicial scrutiny
issues that may limit its ability to entertain recommendations to alter
the focus of its current bidding preferences.
a. Minority- and Women-Owned Businesses and Rural Telephone Companies
68. Section 309(j)(4)(D) of the Act directs the Commission to
consider the use of bidding preferences to ensure that small
businesses, rural telephone companies, and businesses owned by members
of minority groups and women are given the opportunity to participate
in the provision of spectrum-based services. The Commission seeks
comment on whether the current small business provisions are sufficient
to promote participation by businesses owned by minorities and women,
as well as rural telephone companies. To the extent that commenters
propose additional provisions to ensure participation by minority-owned
or women-owned businesses, they should address how such provisions
could be crafted to meet the relevant standards of judicial review. The
Commission asks commenters advocating for the adoption of rural bidding
credits to supply data demonstrating that rural telephone companies
lack access to capital or face barriers to capital formation similar to
those faced by other DEs.
b. Unserved/Underserved Areas and Persistent Poverty Preferences
69. The Commission seeks comment on whether it should extend
bidding credits to winning bidders that deploy facilities and provide
service to unserved or underserved areas. If the Commission adopts
bidding credits for service to unserved or underserved areas what
criteria should it consider to determine if an area is unserved or
underserved? Should any unserved/
[[Page 68184]]
underserved area bidding credits be available in all areas lacking
service, only in rural areas, or only in persistently poor counties? As
required of providers awarded universal service funds through the
Mobility Fund Phase I auctions, should a wireless provider awarded an
unserved/underserved bidding credit be required to provide a certain
level of service (e.g., 3G or 4G) by a certain time frame (e.g., two or
three years) in order to retain the benefit of the bidding credit?
70. The Commission also seeks comment on whether the Commission
should offer a bidding credit to winning bidders that will use their
licensed spectrum to deploy service to persistent poverty counties. As
defined by the Department of Agriculture's Economic Research Service
(ERS), a county is persistently poor if 20 percent or more of its
population was living in poverty over the last 30 years. According to
the ERS, ``there are currently 353 persistently poor counties in the
United States (comprising 11.2 percent of all U.S. counties).'' The ERS
further explains that ``[t]he large majority (301 or 85.3 percent) of
the persistent-poverty counties are nonmetro, accounting for 15.2
percent of all nonmetro counties. Persistent poverty also demonstrates
a strong regional pattern, with nearly 84 percent of persistent-poverty
counties in the South, comprising of more than 20 percent of all
counties in the region.'' The ERS information is available on the ERS
Web site under ``Geography of Poverty,'' at https://www.ers.usda.gov/topics/rural-economy-population/rural-poverty-well-being/geography-of-poverty.aspx. If the Commission adopts such a bidding credit, should it
impose strict performance requirements on providers awarded bidding
credits for licenses covering persistent poverty counties similar to
those required of winning bidders awarded Tribal land bidding credits?
Should this type of bidding credit only apply to licenses covering
persistent poverty counties that are only served by two or fewer
wireless service providers?
71. If the Commission adopts unserved/underserved area and/or
persistent poverty county bidding credits, should the bidding credits
be available only to small businesses and/or other DEs, or to any
applicant? How would the Commission calculate the credit amount where
the unserved or underserved area or targeted counties cover a portion
of a license area? Should the bidding credit be applied to the total
amount of the winning bid for a license, or should it be applied to a
portion of the winning bid based on a percentage of population or
square miles of the license area covered by the unserved/underserved
area or identified counties or some other metric? What size bidding
credit would be appropriate for either an unserved/underserved area
bidding credit or a persistent poverty county bidding credit? If an
applicant qualifies for both bidding credits, should the Commission
limit the amount of the combined credit? Similarly, if an applicant
qualifies for one of these credits in addition to a small business
bidding credit, should the credits be cumulative and, if so, should
there be a limit on the amount of the aggregate bidding credit
provided? Should any limit be an amount greater than the maximum small
business bidding credit to allow DEs eligible for the highest bidding
credit tier to receive an increased benefit for also providing service
to an unserved/underserved area and/or persistent poverty county?
Commenters supporting cumulative bidding credits should provide data or
support justifying the need for higher bidding credits in unserved/
underserved and/or persistent poverty areas. Alternatively, are issues
relating to lack of deployment or low levels of deployment of wireless
services in rural and poor areas better addressed through means other
than the Commission's bidding credit program, such as through service-
specific build-out requirements or reliance on incentives through its
Mobility Fund and other universal service programs?
72. The Commission seeks comment on its authority to implement
these types of bidding preferences. The Commission notes that it has
previously implemented bidding credits based on other criteria than
business size in order to facilitate service to Tribal lands. See In
the Matter of Extending Wireless Telecommunications Services to Tribal
Lands, 65 FR 47366, May 2, 2003 (Tribal Lands Report and Order). In
that proceeding, the Commission found that the objectives and
requirements of section 309(j) of the Act, which the Commission must
consider in designing competitive bidding systems, authorized it to
grant bidding credits targeted specifically to entities that commit to
bringing much needed wireless telecommunications services to Tribal
lands. Specifically, in the Tribal Lands Report and Order, the
Commission found that Tribal Land bidding credits further the objective
of section 309(j)(3)(A) to ensure ``the development and rapid
deployment of new technologies, products, and services for the benefit
of the public, including those residing in rural areas. . . .'' and the
objective of section 309(j)(3)(D) of promoting ``efficient and
intensive use of the electromagnetic spectrum.'' The Commission also
found that there is no indication in section 309(j)(4)(D) or in its
legislative history that the Commission's authority to award bidding
preferences is limited to small businesses, rural telephone companies,
and businesses owned by members of minority groups and women. As such,
the Commission tentatively concludes that section 309(j) of the Act
similarly authorizes the Commission to provide bidding credits for
service to unserved/underserved areas and persistent poverty counties.
The Commission seeks comment on its tentative conclusion.
c. Overcoming Disadvantages Preference
73. In view of renewed interest raised in the BIA proceeding, the
Commission also seeks additional comment on the 2010 Recommendation by
the FCC's Advisory Committee on Diversity for Communications in the
Digital Age (2010 Recommendation) to implement a bidding preference for
persons or entities who have overcome substantial disadvantage
(referred to herein as an overcoming disadvantages preference or ODP).
In that 2010 Recommendation, the Committee proposed that the Commission
should provide an auction bidding credit for otherwise qualified
persons or entities that have overcome substantial disadvantages, to
allow them to compete on equal footing with other applicants. The
Committee stated that an ODP would provide a fair opportunity for
highly qualified applicants to compete for spectrum licenses, thereby
expanding the pool of eligible bidders in an auction. The 2010
Recommendation is available at https://www.fcc.gov/DiversityFAC/meeting101410.html. The Media and Wireless Telecommunications Bureaus
subsequently issued a public notice seeking comment on additional
information that would be helpful in evaluating whether and how to
pursue the Committee's proposal: The Overcoming Disadvantage Preference
Public Notice, 75 FR 81274, Dec. 27, 2010.
74. Commenters should specifically address the Commission's
statutory authority to adopt such a preference and how such a
preference could be crafted to meet the relevant standards of judicial
review. Would a preference for those who have overcome a substantial
disadvantage be subject to a ``rational basis'' constitutional
standard, as the 2010 Recommendation indicates? Additionally, the
Commission seeks detailed comment on how the
[[Page 68185]]
preference would provide additional opportunities not available under
the current bidding credit program, particularly if the current program
is amended as proposed in the Competitive Bidding NPRM.
75. The Commission also asks for input on how it might
systematically collect and maintain data in order to implement and
administer an ODP. What legal basis does it have to collect data, and
what precise data would the Commission need to support such a proposal?
76. The Commission asks commenters to address how eligibility for
an ODP could be demonstrated, providing specific information as to what
definitions of disadvantages could qualify individuals or entities for
the preference. How would it measure when any particular disadvantage
had been overcome? The 2010 Recommendation provides a non-exhaustive
list that includes disadvantages such as physical disabilities or
psychological disorders that rendered professional or business
advancement substantially more difficult than for most individuals. How
could the Commission avoid subjective determinations and implement and
apply an ODP on a neutral basis? The Commission asks commenters to
discuss how it could establish eligibility for the preference
objectively. How could the Commission render eligibility determinations
for an ODP without appearing arbitrary? How could it safeguard any such
benefits to ensure they are awarded only to eligible persons or
entities?
77. The Commission also seeks detailed comment on how it could
administer an ODP. Commenters should identify the costs and benefits
associated with such a program, addressing matters such as how reviews
would be conducted, and the nature of the demonstration applicants
seeking a preference would be required to make, as well as how
individualized evaluation for the preference would be incorporated into
a time-sensitive short-form application process or whether alternatives
such as pre-qualification would be necessary.
78. As acknowledged by the Advisory Committee, its ODP proposal
raises a number of issues that need to be refined and resolved in order
to design and implement such a preference, and comment provided to date
has not provided sufficient basis or justification for doing so.
Therefore, commenters that continue to support the adoption of an ODP
are encouraged to provide as detailed and specific suggestions as
possible regarding the Commission's authority to establish the ODP and
its objectives in doing so, as well as eligibility for, and
administration of, the preference, to assist the Commission in
determining a legal, neutral, and efficient way in which it could
implement an ODP. Alternatively, the Commission asks commenters to
consider whether the proposals the Commission has made to amend its
existing DE program would obviate the need for the adoption of such a
preference.
D. DE Reporting Requirements
79. Background. Section 1.2110(n) requires DE licensees to file an
annual report with the Commission that includes, at a minimum, a list
and summaries of all agreements and arrangements, extant or proposed,
that relate to eligibility for DE benefits. The list must include the
parties (including affiliates, controlling interests, and affiliates of
controlling interests) to each agreement or arrangement, as well as the
dates on which the parties entered into each agreement or arrangement.
DEs are required to file a report for each of their licenses no later
than, and up to five business days before, the anniversary of the date
of license grant.
80. Discussion. The Commission proposes to repeal this reporting
requirement. The information DEs are required to include in their
annual reports is duplicative of information that they provide in their
auction and license applications. See 47 CFR 1.2110(j),
1.2112(b)(2)(iii). In addition, before entering into leases or other
agreements that might affect their eligibility, DEs must seek
Commission approval and must list and summarize those agreements,
including the parties to and the dates of the agreements. See 47 CFR
1.2114. Moreover, for licensees with multiple auction licenses, each
having a different grant date, the burden of the annual reporting
requirement is exacerbated by the obligation to file multiple reports
each year. For these reasons, the Commission tentatively concludes that
the value of the information provided in these annual reports may no
longer outweigh the reporting burden that they impose on DEs.
81. The Commission seeks comment on its proposal. In particular,
commenters are invited to address whether there are any benefits to
retaining the annual reporting requirement that the Commission has
failed to consider. Does this reporting requirement in any way help the
Commission identify agreements between parties relating to small
business eligibility that might otherwise escape attention? Commenters
should specifically address how other rules render this reporting
requirement duplicative and how other rules adequately ensure that the
Commission is aware of all agreements between parties relating to small
business eligibility. Will relieving DEs of this annual reporting
requirement reduce their regulatory burdens to any measurable degree?
Without this reporting requirement, will the Commission continue to
have the necessary tools to safeguard DE benefits from unjustly
enriching ineligible entities? If the Commission adopts this proposal
to eliminate this annual reporting requirement, should the Commission
amend the requirement in 47 CFR 1.2114 that a small business list and
summarize all existing agreements to provide context each time it
reports a new eligibility event?
E. MMTC's White Paper Requests
82. Background. In February 2014, MMTC submitted a White Paper
detailing several policy recommendations to advance minority and women
spectrum license ownership. In addition to requesting the elimination
of the AMR, an increase in bidding credits, and a substantive review of
proposed DE rules, the White Paper requests Commission action in the
following areas: (1) Reinstitute select DE-only closed spectrum
auctions; (2) Incorporate diversity and inclusion in the Commission's
public interest analysis of mergers and acquisitions (M&As) and
secondary market spectrum transactions; (3) Conduct ongoing
recordkeeping of DE performance; (4) Complete the Adarand Studies,
updating the section 257 studies released in 2000; (5) Regularize
procedural requirements; and (6) Support increased funding for and
statutory amendments regarding the Telecommunications Development Fund.
The Commission notes that MMTC's above request with respect to
``ongoing recordkeeping of DE performance'' refers to retaining
specific information about minority- and woman-owned business
enterprise bidders, in addition to the small business status.
83. Discussion. The Commission seeks comment on the proposals that
are not otherwise addressed in the NPRM, and to the extent that they
relate to its competitive bidding rules. The Commission observes that
certain proposals appear to be outside the scope of this proceeding and
others may not be needed in light of other changes proposed herein.
Toward that end, the Commission tentatively concludes that the
following MMTC proposals are
[[Page 68186]]
outside the scope of this proceeding, which is focused on its
competitive bidding rules, and thus will not be addressed here: (1)
Incorporating diversity and inclusion in the Commission's public
interest analysis of mergers and acquisitions and secondary market
spectrum transactions; and (2) supporting increased funding for and
statutory amendments regarding the Telecommunications Development Fund.
The Commission seeks comment on MMTC's additional requests, including
discussion regarding the relative costs and benefits of each proposal.
Are the proposals that the Commission describes elsewhere in the NPRM,
including the elimination of the AMR rule, sufficient to address the
concerns identified by MMTC regarding the participation of businesses
owned by members of minority groups and women in the provision of
spectrum-based services?
III. Other Part 1 Considerations
84. In advance of an auction that could hold historic potential for
interested applicants to acquire licenses for below-1-GHz spectrum, the
Commission also explores the need for other revisions to its general
part 1 competitive bidding rules to improve the transparency and
efficiency of the auction and its processes. The Commission proposes
changes to its former defaulter rule that seek to balance commenters'
concerns that the current rules are overly broad with its continued
need to ensure that auction bidders are financially reliable. The
Commission also proposes to codify an existing competitive bidding
procedure that prohibits the same individual or entity from filing more
than one short-form application to participate in an auction and it
proposes a new rule that would prevent entities that are exclusively
controlled by a single individual or set of individuals from becoming
qualified to bid on the basis of more than one short-form application
in a specific auction. Both proposals seek to prevent duplicative
filings and to avert anticompetitive bidding behavior at auction.
Regarding the joint bidding rules, the Commission seeks comment on,
among other issues, its tentative conclusions that it would be in the
public interest to retain the current rules governing joint bidding
arrangements among non-nationwide providers and to prohibit joint
bidding arrangements among nationwide providers. Additionally, the
Commission provides notice of its intention to resolve long standing
petitions for reconsideration and proposes necessary clean-up revisions
to its part 1 competitive bidding rules.
A. Former Defaulter Rule
85. Background. Each potential participant in a Commission auction
must certify on its pre-auction short-form application whether or not
the applicant, its affiliates, its controlling interests, and the
affiliates of its controlling interests have ever been in default on
any Commission license or have ever been delinquent on any non-tax debt
owed to any federal agency. With the exception of the Commission's
upcoming auction for AWS-3 licenses (Auction 97) for which it recently
granted a limited blanket waiver, an applicant is considered to be a
``former defaulter'' if the applicant, including any of its affiliates,
its controlling interests, or any of the affiliates of its controlling
interests, has defaulted on any Commission license or been delinquent
on any non-tax debt owed to any federal agency, but has since remedied
all such defaults and cured all of its outstanding non-tax
delinquencies. Former defaulters are eligible to bid in a Commission
auction provided they are otherwise qualified, but are required to pay
upfront payments that are 50 percent more than the normal upfront
payment amounts.
86. In the Part 1 Fifth Report and Order, the ``former defaulter''
policies were incorporated into the Commission's part 1 general
competitive bidding rules. See Amendment of Part 1 of the Commission's
Rules--Competitive Bidding Procedures, 65 FR 52323, Aug. 29, 2000 (Part
1 Fifth Report and Order). The Commission reasoned that the integrity
of the auctions program and the licensing process dictates requiring a
more stringent financial showing from applicants with a poor federal
financial track record. Thus, while cure of an outstanding federal
default or delinquency enables the former defaulter to participate in
an auction, the rules require the former defaulter to make a larger
upfront payment. Other than in the recent waiver for Auction 97, the
former defaulter rule has been applied without any limitation as to age
or scope of an applicant's prior default or delinquency.
87. On August 29, 2014, in response to unopposed requests from
wireless industry parties, the Commission granted a limited blanket
waiver to narrow the circumstances under which an applicant for Auction
97 would be considered a former defaulter and required to submit a
larger upfront payment to qualify to bid. The Commission concluded that
the underlying purpose of the upfront payment and former defaulter
rules would not be served by their broad application in the AWS-3
auction, and that a limited waiver served the public interest.
Specifically, for Auction 97, the Commission waived the former
defaulter rule for applicants to exclude any cured default or
delinquency for which any of the following criteria were met: (1) The
notice of the final payment deadline or delinquency was received more
than seven years before the Auction 97 short-form application deadline
of September 12, 2014; (2) the amount of the default or delinquency
falls below $100,000; (3) the default or delinquency was paid within
two quarters (i.e., 6 months) after receiving the notice of the final
payment deadline or delinquency; or (4) the default or delinquency was
the subject of a legal or arbitration proceeding that was cured upon
resolution of the proceeding. See Petition of DIRECTV Group, Inc. and
EchoStar LLC (collectively, DIRECTV/EchoStar) for Expedited Rulemaking
to Amend Section 1.2105(a)(2)(xi) and 1.2106(a) of the Commission's
Rules and/or for Interim Condition Waiver; Auction of Advanced Wireless
Services (AWS-3) Licenses Scheduled for November 13, 2014 (Auction 97),
RM-11395; AU Docket No. 14-78, Order, FCC 14-130, para. 1 (rel. Aug.
29, 2014) (Auction 97 Former Defaulter Waiver Order). Pursuant to the
Auction 97 Former Defaulter Waiver Order, only applicants that have had
a cured default or delinquency that falls outside of these exclusions
would have to certify to being a ``former defaulter'' and submit a
larger upfront payment in Auction 97. The Auction 97 Former Defaulter
Waiver Order noted that the Commission's limited grant of the blanket
waiver for Auction 97 was without prejudice to its further examination
and disposition, based on a complete record, of the issues surrounding
the former defaulter rule through a rulemaking proceeding.
88. Discussion. Although the former defaulter rule serves an
important and necessary function to ensure that bidders are capable of
meeting their financial commitments, the Commission tentatively
concludes that the rule may be too far-reaching and impose unnecessary
costs and burdens on auction participants. The Commission proposes a
more tailored approach by balancing concerns that the current
application of the rule is overbroad with its continued need to ensure
that auction bidders are financially reliable. The Commission seeks
comment on revising the rule to narrow the scope of
[[Page 68187]]
the defaults and delinquencies that will be considered in determining
whether or not an auction participant is a former defaulter.
Specifically, the Commission proposes to exclude any cured default on
any Commission license or delinquency on any non-tax debt owed to any
federal agency for which any of the following criteria are met: (1) The
notice of the final payment deadline or delinquency was received more
than seven years before the relevant short-form application deadline;
(2) the default or delinquency amounted to less than $100,000; (3) the
default or delinquency was paid within two quarters (i.e., 6 months)
after receiving the notice of the final payment deadline or
delinquency; or (4) the default or delinquency was the subject of a
legal or arbitration proceeding that was cured upon resolution of the
proceeding. The Commission seeks comment on limiting the individuals
and entities that an applicant must consider when determining its
status as a former defaulter.
89. In offering these proposals to limit the former defaulter rule,
the Commission keeps in mind the underlying purposes of the upfront
payment rule generally, and the increased upfront payment required of
former defaulters. The Commission typically requires auction
participants to provide upfront payments in order to qualify to bid in
an auction. Upfront payments help prevent frivolous or insincere
bidding and provide the Commission with a source of funds from which to
collect payments owed at the close of auction. In adopting an upfront
payment requirement, the Commission also recognized that it was
balancing the goal of encouraging bidders to submit serious, qualified
bids with the desire to simplify the bidding process and minimize
implementation costs that will be imposed on bidders. The original
former defaulter rule appeared in the Commission's part 24 Broadband
PCS rules in the wake of financial difficulties of participants in the
C Block auctions. The Commission subsequently incorporated the part 24
former defaulter policies into the part 1 general competitive bidding
rules, noting that the rule's purpose was to preserve the integrity of
the auction process and ensure that bidders are capable of meeting
their financial commitments to the Commission. As the Commission noted
in the Auction 97 Former Defaulter Waiver Order, in the 14 years since
that Commission action, its auctions program has matured and the mobile
wireless industry has grown into a major segment of the nation's
economy. Accordingly, the Commission considers in the Competitive
Bidding NPRM whether the current broad rule continues to strike the
right balance to promote the goals of its upfront payment and former
defaulter rule.
90. The parties that requested waiver of the former defaulter rule
also suggest that the Commission modify the rule. For instance, in
their petition, DIRECTV/EchoStar argue that, as currently written, the
former defaulter rule applies too broadly to effectively advance the
Commission's goal of ensuring that auction bidders are financially
reliable. In their joint filing, CCA, CEA, CTIA and NTCA (the Four
Associations) mirror that sentiment and suggest that the scope of the
rule is unnecessary to achieve its purpose, particularly when the
former defaults or delinquencies are in a relatively small amount or
were cured years prior. These parties offer a variety of ways to limit
the scope of the former defaulter inquiry, but all consistently contend
that the rule is unnecessarily broad to serve its underlying purpose.
The Commission seeks comment on its specific proposals to narrow the
scope of the defaults and delinquencies that would trigger an auction
applicant's former defaulter status and asks commenters to address
whether, if such proposals are adopted, the Commission can still
promote the important protective functions of its upfront payment and
former defaulter rules.
91. Parties urge first that prior delinquencies and defaults more
than a certain number of years old should be excluded from the scope of
the former defaulter rule. In the Auction 97 Former Defaulter Waiver
Order, the Commission excluded from consideration under the former
defaulter rule any cured default or delinquency for which the notice of
the final payment deadline or delinquency was received more than seven
years before the Auction 97 short-form application deadline of
September 12, 2014. The Commission concluded that the rule's current
unlimited time period may capture former defaults and delinquencies
that have lost their relevance to a bidder's current capability to meet
its financial commitments to the Commission, and thus may no longer
warrant a larger upfront payment for Auction 97. Initially, advocates
seeking a more limited time frame for the rule's application argued
that a three year period would correspond to certain Federal tax
statute of limitations. In seeking a waiver for Auction 97, CCA, CTIA
and NTCA (the Three Associations) suggested that the Commission should
define former defaulters to include only those applicants who have
received notice of defaults or delinquencies within seven years before
the Auction 97 short-form application deadline. In the Auction 97
Former Defaulter Waiver Order, the Commission noted that while federal
tax laws have a three-year statute of limitations to determine if
certain forms of additional tax are owed, the period of limitations to
determine whether income was under-reported is six years and the
Internal Revenue Service has a seven-year period to review a claim for
a loss from worthless securities or a bad debt deduction. Likewise, the
Commission acknowledged that the Fair Credit Reporting Act limits many
types of reporting by consumer credit agencies for a period of seven
years. In light of these longer federal limitations periods, the
Commission tentatively concludes that the purposes of the upfront
payment and former defaulter rules may be furthered more precisely if
the Commission excludes any cured default on a Commission license or a
delinquency on a non-tax debt owed to a federal agency where the notice
of the final payment deadline or delinquency was received more than
seven years before the short-form application deadline. In doing so,
the Commission notes that the determination of a notice of a final
payment deadline or delinquency depends on the origin of the federal
non-tax debt giving rise to a default or delinquency and such notice
may be express or implied. To the extent that the rules providing for
payment of a specific federal debt permit payment after an original
payment deadline accompanied by late fee(s), such debts would not be in
default or delinquent for purposes of applying the former defaulter
rules until after the late payment deadline. For the purposes of the
certifications required on a short-form auction application, notice
provided by Commission staff assessing a default payment arising out of
a default on a winning bid constitutes notice of the final payment
deadline with respect to a default on a Commission license. The
Commission seeks comment on all aspects of this proposal--the number of
years specified (seven), the triggering event (upon receipt of the
notice of the final payment deadline or delinquency), and the point at
which the counting of the age of the triggering event is cut off (the
short-form application deadline). To the extent commenters advocate a
different length of time, an alternate triggering event, or another way
of calculating how long ago the triggering event
[[Page 68188]]
occurred, the Commission urges them to be specific as to why their
proposal is more appropriate given the policies behind its rule. Should
the length of time it took the defaulter to cure the debt, or how
recently the cure occurred, be a factor?
92. Those favoring modification of the rule also suggest excluding
former defaults or delinquencies that fall below a certain amount. The
Auction 97 Former Defaulter Waiver Order excluded from consideration
under the former defaulter rule for Auction 97 any former default or
delinquency for which the amount of the resolved debt or delinquency
fell below $100,000. Parties initially suggested excluding defaults or
delinquencies of what they defined as de minimis in nature, and
specifically suggested that the Commission should ignore any former
default or delinquency totaling less than the lesser of $100,000 or 0.1
percent of the average annual revenues of the applicant, as computed by
its competitive bidding rules. The Three Associations later suggested
that the Commission exclude from the definition of former defaulter any
cured defaults on a Commission license or delinquencies on a non-tax
debt owed to a federal agency in an amount of less than $100,000. In
the Auction 97 Former Defaulter Waiver Order, the Commission noted the
$100,000 amount is used in other contexts to distinguish between less
significant or material issues and more significant ones and the
Commission concluded that for the purposes of Auction 97, requiring a
larger upfront payment based on any cured default or delinquency that
is less than $100,000 could discourage participation in Auction 97
without appreciably ameliorating the risk of bidder defaults, and
thereby undermine the underlying purposes of its upfront payment and
former defaulter rules.
93. For clarity and efficiency of the administration of the former
defaulter rule from both the Commission's and applicants' perspectives,
the Commission now proposes to adopt for future auctions generally the
same bright-line standard established in the Auction 97 Former
Defaulter Waiver Order that would exclude from the rule any former
default on a Commission license or delinquency on a non-tax debt owed
to a federal agency where the amount of the resolved debt falls below
$100,000. The Commission tentatively concludes that such an exclusion
will simplify the application process and minimize implementation costs
imposed on applicants by excluding former defaults and delinquencies
for which consideration is no longer necessary to ensure bidders in a
more mature wireless industry submit serious, qualified bids. The
$100,000 threshold aligns with Commission precedent and is used in
other contexts to determine the materiality or significance of various
issues. See Auction 97 Former Defaulter Waiver Order at para. 18. If
commenters disagree with the amount proposed, the Commission encourages
them to provide specific examples of how former defaults or
delinquencies of a different amount would better reflect an auction
applicant's financial reliability. The Commission also seeks comment on
whether its proposal adequately weighs its need to consider debts of a
serious nature that are indicative of a bidder's poor federal track
record with the burdens faced by many applicants in complying with the
current rule, which might be considered open-ended in scope.
94. To address situations where, due to incorrect addresses,
delivery problems, or internal issues, applicants may not timely pay
obligations, but cure such debts when discovered, the Three
Associations also contend that the Commission should for the purposes
of the former defaulter rule exclude certain additional resolved debts.
For Auction 97 applicants, the Commission waived the former defaulter
rule to exclude any cured default or delinquency where the debt was
paid within two quarters (i.e., 6 months) after receiving the notice of
final payment deadline or delinquency. There, the Commission concluded
that the prompt cure of such a default or delinquency sufficiently
demonstrated an applicant's financial wherewithal, that therefore it
was unnecessary to require a larger upfront payment from the applicant,
and that a waiver under such circumstances served the public interest
by encouraging prompt payment of debts owed to the government. The
Commission now proposes to modify the former defaulter rule generally
to exclude a default or delinquency that was paid within two quarters
(i.e., 6 months) after receiving the notice of the final payment
deadline or delinquency for the same reasons articulated in the Auction
97 Former Defaulter Waiver Order. The Commission seeks comment on
whether this exclusion will allow it to appropriately balance the
practicalities that may affect the applicants' ability to timely
resolve their debts with the need to ensure that bidders are capable of
meeting their financial commitments to the Commission. The Commission
also invites commenters to address whether payment within some other
time period might better strike that balance, and whether receipt of
the notice of the final payment deadline or delinquency is the
appropriate triggering event for this exclusion.
95. Similarly, the Three Associations also suggest for the purposes
of modifying the former defaulter rule that an applicant should not be
considered to be in default if any debt is the subject of a good faith
dispute or a pending legal or arbitration proceeding. In the Auction 97
Former Defaulter Waiver Order, the Commission included this suggestion
in part, and concluded that where the default or delinquency was the
subject of a legal or arbitration proceeding and was cured upon
resolution of the proceeding, an applicant has demonstrated sufficient
financial credibility so that it was not necessary to require a larger
upfront payment from it in Auction 97. The Commission determined that
waiver under such circumstances served the public interest by
encouraging prompt resolution of debts associated with legal or
arbitration proceedings. The Commission declined, however, to waive the
larger upfront payment requirement for debts that are subject to a
``good faith dispute'' because it reasoned that such a provision, even
for cured debts, would be too ambiguous to be efficiently applied
during the auction short-form application process. The Commission
proposes to modify the former defaulter rule generally to exclude a
default or delinquency that was the subject of a legal or arbitration
proceeding and was cured upon resolution of the proceeding. As in the
Auction 97 Former Defaulter Waiver Order, the Commission does not
intend to include within the scope of this exclusion any proceedings
based on requests for waiver of a rule requiring payment of a debt or
delinquency. The Commission seeks comment on whether its proposed
exclusion addresses parties' concerns that debts such as these are not
indicative of an applicant's financial credibility such that they
should require an applicant to submit a larger upfront payment. Should
the Commission also exclude debts cured after resolution of a ``good
faith dispute,'' and if so, how could such ``good faith disputes'' be
verified during the short-form application process, if necessary? Is
the proposed general exclusion for debts cured upon resolution of a
legal or arbitration proceeding necessary? In the alternative, should
the Commission expect financially reliable applicants to pay
outstanding defaults on Commission licenses, or delinquencies on any
non-
[[Page 68189]]
tax debt owed to any federal agency, while legal or arbitration
proceedings are pending, even if the applicant's liability or the
amount of the debt is in dispute?
96. In their petition, DIRECTV/EchoStar also maintain that the
former defaulter rule should apply only to auction participants and
those individuals or entities that are in a position to affect whether
such applicants meet their auction-related financial responsibilities
and urge the exclusion of debts/delinquencies relating to personal
obligations of officers or directors of entities that are not the
auction applicant, e.g., excluding personal obligations of officers and
directors of the applicant's parent companies. More recent requests to
amend the former defaulter rule do not include any suggestion to limit
the scope of individuals and entities that an applicant needs to
consider in evaluating its former defaulter status.
97. In implementing the former defaulter provisions, the Commission
has included the applicant's affiliates, its controlling interests, and
affiliates of its controlling interests in determining if an applicant
is a former defaulter. The Commission recognizes, however, that some of
the individuals and entities that fall within these definitions may
play no role in the applicant's general financial responsibilities and
may not affect an applicant's ability to meet its financial obligations
arising from an auction. Therefore, the Commission seeks comment on
possible ways to amend the former defaulter provisions to apply only to
individuals and entities that play a role in the applicant's financial
responsibilities. If the Commission were to adopt DIRECTV/EchoStar's
proposal to include only individuals or entities that are in a position
to affect whether such applicants meet their auction-related financial
responsibilities, how could it verify who would fit within such a
category? In their request for waiver, DIRECTV/EchoStar suggest
specifically not applying the rule to officers and directors of parent
entities. Under such an option, however, what would prevent applicants
from evading the rule by simply creating a shell company to be the
auction applicant?
98. Another option would be to limit the former defaulter inquiry
to those individuals or entities that an applicant must disclose on its
short-form application pursuant to 47 CFR 1.2112. For non-DEs, this
would limit the inquiry to the applicant and disclosable interest
holders under 47 CFR 1.2112(a). For DEs, the Commission could, under
this option, continue to include those individuals and entities that
are attributable to the applicant under 47 CFR 1.2112(b)(iv) in any
consideration of an applicant's form defaulter status. As such, the
Commission recognizes that, while such an option may exclude some
individuals and entities not directly related to an applicant's auction
finances, it could also expand the scope of individuals or entities
that must be considered in some respects. The Commission could limit
the inquiry to, for example, the real party or parties in interest in
the applicant or application, which must be disclosed pursuant to 47
CFR 1.2112(a)(1). Would this option capture the individuals and
entities that are in a position to affect whether an applicant meets
its auction-related financial responsibilities? Would excluding
officers and directors not otherwise covered by 47 CFR1.2112(a)(1) be
inconsistent with the Commission's policy to attribute them for
purposes of evaluating eligibility for designated entity bidding
credits in light of their potential ability to influence the management
or operation of the applicant?
99. Finally, the Commission seeks comment as to other possible ways
to limit the scope of the former defaulter rule. For example, the
Commission could define the rules to include only defaults or
delinquencies related to its auction payments, or defaults or
delinquencies on debt owed only to the Commission as opposed to those
owed on other government non-tax debt, such as student loans. The
Commission notes, however, that such further limitations may not be
necessary given the other limitations that it proposes.
B. Commonly Controlled Entities
100. The Commission proposes to codify an established competitive
bidding procedure that prohibits the same individual or entity from
filing more than one short-form application. Additionally, the
Commission proposes a new rule that would prevent entities that are
exclusively controlled by a single individual or set of individuals
from qualifying to bid on licenses in the same or overlapping
geographic areas in a specific auction on more than one short-form
application.
101. Background. The Commission's competitive bidding procedures
have long prohibited the same individual or entity from submitting
multiple short-form applications in any auction. This restriction
prevents duplicative filings and may avert anticompetitive bidding
behavior.
102. There is currently no similar procedure for commonly
controlled entities. The competitive bidding rules and procedures
currently contain no explicit prohibition on commonly controlled
entities participating in the same auction and bidding on the same
licenses. Several years ago, the Commission declined to set aside the
results of an auction based on allegations relating to the
participation of separate applicants that were commonly controlled. In
that decision, the Commission acknowledged that auction participation
by commonly controlled applicants could serve legitimate business
purposes if such entities have different business plans, financing
requirements, or marketing needs; however, it noted that there could be
risks inherent in allowing commonly controlled bidders to participate
in an auction. See Petition for Reconsideration and Motion for Stay of
Paging Systems, Inc., Memorandum Opinion and Order, 25 FCC Rcd 4036
(2010).
103. Discussion. The Commission proposes to amend its competitive
bidding rules to codify its restriction on the filing of multiple
auction applications by the same individual or entity and to adopt a
new rule that would prevent entities that are controlled exclusively by
the same single individual or set of individuals from qualifying to bid
based on multiple auction applications for the same or overlapping
geographic license areas. By proposing these amendments to its Part 1
competitive bidding rules, the Commission seeks to improve the
transparency and efficiency of the auction process, by making clearer
who the qualified bidders actually are and ensuring against the
potential for anticompetitive auction behavior.
104. Duplicate auction applications. The Commission proposes to
amend 47 CFR 1.2105 to prohibit the same individual or entity from
filing more than one short-form application for an auction. The
Commission observes that in contexts other than competitive bidding,
its rules already limit repetitious or conflicting applications.
Prohibiting the same individual or entity from filing multiple
applications to participate in an auction protects the Commission
against the burden of duplicative, repetitious or conflicting
applications. Moreover, in this context, such applications raise
potential concerns that duplicate filers may be able to manipulate the
auction process--using, for example, identical bids or multiple
activity waivers--to pursue potentially anticompetitive ends. The
Commission seeks comment on this proposal. Are there any specific
reasons the Commission should allow for the filing of more than a
single short-form
[[Page 68190]]
application from the same individual or entity? Commenters should
describe any public interest benefits to support their positions.
105. Applications by entities exclusively controlled by the same
individual or set of individuals. The Commission also proposes to adopt
a new rule to provide that where entities are under the common,
exclusive control of a single individual or set of individuals (i.e., a
single individual or same set of individuals is the exclusive
controlling interest of more than one entity) only one short-form
application from such entities could become qualified to participate
with respect to any particular geographic license area or overlapping
areas. In defining the entities that would be subject to this rule, the
Commission proposes to use the concepts of ``control'' or ``controlling
interest'' from 47 CFR 1.2110, which also applies by its terms to DEs.
Even when applicants are not identical, if more than one applicant is
under the exclusive control of a single individual or set of
individuals, such common control may allow the controlling individual
or set of individuals to attempt to gain advantages in the bidding
process based on certain coordinated bidding actions (e.g., tied bids,
activity waivers). While such entities may have different business
plans, financing, accounting, non-controlling interest holders or
minority investors, if they are under exclusive control of a single
individual or set of individuals, under the Commission's proposal those
entities could not become qualified to bid in an auction with respect
to the same or overlapping geographic license areas. The Commission
seeks comment on this proposal and on specific alternatives to address
its concerns.
106. Multiple applicants under the common control of a single
individual or set of individuals may coordinate their bidding actions
in ways not available to a single bidder, and may, in some cases,
derive some advantage from doing so. For example, such multiple
applicants would have more activity waivers to use to ensure that the
auction remains open, or would be able to submit identical bids on a
license in ways intended to exploit auction bidding procedures. In
addition, such multiple applicants could potentially coordinate their
bidding to gain some advantage in the context of random tie-breakers or
through increasing the bidding activity on a single license in order to
raise minimum acceptable bids more quickly through application of the
exponential smoothing formula.
107. Further, the mere presence of commonly controlled applicants
making identical bids in a single auction may damage the transparency
of the auction process. For example, the placing of multiple identical
bids by commonly controlled applicants may mislead other bidders about
the extent of bidding competition, especially in an anonymous bidding
auction where competitors are unable to discern whether bids are placed
by commonly controlled applicants or independent competitors. The
Commission anticipates that these and other potentially problematic
behaviors could be curbed by requiring such applicants to participate
as a single applicant with respect to any particular geographic license
area or overlapping areas.
108. Do commenters share the Commission's concern that the
participation of commonly controlled applicants in an auction
potentially undermines evenhandedness and transparency in the auction
process? Commenters opposing the Commission's proposals should indicate
how codifying its existing auction procedure and/or adopting its new
proposed rule would harm the efficiency or undermine the
competitiveness of the Commission's current auction process. The
Commission notes that to the extent that the commonly controlled
entities have an interest in holding licenses won at auction
separately, such entities might consider assigning the licenses to
related entities in the secondary market. Are there legitimate business
reasons for filing these types of applications that the Commission has
failed to consider that could be undermined by its proposal?
C. Joint Bidding
109. The Commission initiates a review of its rules and policies
governing joint bidding and other arrangements in order to ensure that
they fulfill its statutory objectives, given the changes in the mobile
wireless marketplace since the Commission's initial adoption of its
bidding rules two decades ago, and the increasing importance of
spectrum for service providers to meet consumer demand for mobile
wireless services. The Commission's goal in reviewing these rules and
policies is to ensure that they preserve and promote competition in the
mobile wireless marketplace and facilitate competition among bidders at
auction, while providing potential bidders with greater clarity
regarding the types of joint bidding arrangements that would be
permissible.
110. Consistent with the Commission's commitment in the Mobile
Spectrum Holdings Report and Order, it seeks to develop a record on how
joint bidding and other arrangements affect competition in the mobile
wireless marketplace, and the appropriate policies and procedures for
substantive competitive review of joint bidding. Policies Regarding
Mobile Spectrum Holdings; Expanding the Economic and Innovation
Opportunities of Spectrum Through Incentive Auctions, 79 FR 39977, Jul.
11, 2014 (Mobile Spectrum Holdings Report and Order). In that regard,
the Commission notes that the scope of its inquiry here--unlike its
other proposals in the NPRM applies only to joint bidding and other
arrangements in auctions of licenses likely to be used for mobile
telephony/mobile broadband services.
111. To best serve the public interest and preserve and promote
robust competition, the Commission also proposes to adopt policies
tailored to the characteristics of joint bidding and other arrangements
and the likely competitive effects on the mobile wireless marketplace.
Specifically, the Commission tentatively concludes that it would best
serve the public interest to retain the current rules governing joint
bidding arrangements among non-nationwide providers and to prohibit
joint bidding arrangements among nationwide providers. In addition, the
Commission seeks comment on whether it should revise any of its current
rules as applied to arrangements between nationwide providers and other
entities, including its rules governing short-form applications.
Further, the Commission seeks comment on whether any revisions to its
rules governing long-form applications are necessary in light of its
consideration of the potential harms and benefits of joint bidding and
other arrangements.
112. Background. Rules and Policies Governing Joint Bidding. In
1994, the Commission adopted rules to serve the objectives of the Act
by preventing parties, especially the largest firms, from agreeing in
advance to bidding strategies that divide the market according to their
strategic interests and disadvantage other bidders. See Implementation
of Section 309(j) of the Communications Act--Competitive Bidding, 59 FR
22980, May 4, 1994 (Competitive Bidding Second Report and Order). The
Commission also sought to help ensure that the government receives a
fair market price for the use of the spectrum. In the Competitive
Bidding Second Report and Order, the Commission further concluded that
adopting safeguards to prevent collusive behavior
[[Page 68191]]
among bidders would help ensure prompt delivery of services (including
to rural areas), rapid deployment of new services and technologies,
development of competitive markets, and wide access to a variety of
services. Moreover, the Commission observed that collusive conduct
among bidders could prevent the formation of a competitive post-auction
market structure. At the same time, the Commission recognized that if
anticollusion rules are too strict or are not sufficiently clear, they
could prevent the formation of efficiency enhancing bidding consortia
that pool capital and expertise and reduce entry barriers for small
firms and other entities that might not otherwise be able to compete in
the auction process.
113. The Commission concluded that, in most cases, the number of
bidders likely to participate in the auction, auction design
safeguards, and existing antitrust law would effectively deter
collusion. However, the Commission also adopted certain measures to
help ensure collusion would not jeopardize the competitiveness of the
auction process. Importantly, the Commission found these safeguards
sufficient in the context of other competition-related determinations
it had made regarding the initial licensing of Broadband PCS licenses
through competitive bidding. Specifically, the Commission had set a
limit on the amount of broadband PCS spectrum that the incumbent
cellular licensees in each market could acquire at the upcoming PCS
auctions as well as a separate limit on the amount of such spectrum
that any bidder could acquire at the upcoming Broadband PCS auctions.
In 1991, the Commission had adopted a cellular cross-interest rule that
substantially limited any affiliation between the two cellular
licensees in an area.
114. With relatively minor changes adopted since 1994, the
Commission's current rules allow potential participants in a Commission
auction, prior to the short-form application deadline, to enter into
various kinds of agreements related to the licenses being auctioned as
long as the applicants disclose on the short-form application on both
the existence (but not the terms and conditions) of any joint bidding
arrangements and the real-parties-in-interest to the application. After
the short-form application deadline, applicants may not enter into any
additional arrangements regarding the amount of bids, bidding
strategies or particular licenses on which they will or will not bid,
subject to certain limited exceptions, and may not communicate bidding
information to other applicants for licenses in any of the same
geographic areas unless those other applicant(s) were identified on the
short-form application. Post-auction, winning bidders must disclose on
the long-form application the specific terms, conditions, and parties
involved in any agreement into which the applicant has entered, and the
winning bidder must be the same entity that files the long-form
application.
115. The Commission notes that it has always made clear with
respect to its rules and policies governing joint bidding that conduct
that is permissible under the Commission's Rules may be prohibited by
the antitrust laws, review under which is subject to other and
differing standards under the Sherman and Clayton Acts. Specifically,
joint bidding arrangements under section 1 of the Sherman Act are
prohibited if they constitute a ``contract, combination . . ., or
conspiracy, in restraint of trade,'' whereas joint bidding arrangements
subject to section 7 of the Clayton Act are prohibited if their effect
``may be substantially to lessen competition, or to tend to create a
monopoly.'' The Commission's auction procedures public notices for
specific auctions caution that compliance with the disclosure
requirements of 47 CFR 1.2105(c) will not insulate a party from
enforcement of the antitrust laws. Bidders who are found to have
violated the antitrust laws or the Commission's rules in connection
with their participation in the competitive bidding process may be
subject to forfeiture, prohibition from auction participation, and
other sanctions.
116. Evolution of the Mobile Wireless Marketplace. The Commission
adopted these joint bidding rules 20 years ago when the mobile wireless
industry was at a nascent stage: For example, at the end of 1994, the
nationwide penetration rate for mobile wireless service was
approximately 9 percent, compared to 106 percent at the end of 2011.
Moreover, when the Commission adopted its joint bidding rules in 1994,
it had yet to hold even the first of the numerous auctions it has
conducted in its history of licenses likely to be used for mobile
telephony/mobile broadband services.
117. The Commission's competitive bidding rules, as adopted in
1994, reflected the developing nature of the mobile wireless industry,
as the Commission sought to promote economic growth in the ``new
wireless services'' and to enhance access to telecommunication services
by encouraging broad participation in the provision of spectrum-based
services and ensuring that spectrum-based services are available to a
wide range of consumers. In 1998, the Commission observed again that
much of the mobile telephone market was still in its infancy.
118. Since 1994, and particularly in the past decade, the
marketplace has changed significantly. It is no longer nascent.
Consumer demand for wireless services has exploded, with the industry
focus changing from the provision of mobile voice services to the
provision of mobile broadband services. The adoption of smartphones and
tablet computers, and the widespread use of mobile applications,
combined with the increasing deployment of high-speed 3G and now 4G
technologies, is driving significantly more intensive use of mobile
networks and increasing providers' need for spectrum. In addition,
during the past decade, the wireless marketplace has undergone
significant consolidation, with a reduction from six to four nationwide
providers, an increase in the market share of the major providers, and
a smaller number of regional and local providers. Indeed, by December
2013, the top four facilities-based nationwide providers had combined
market share of approximately 97 percent of subscribers. See UBS
Investment Research, US Wireless 411: Version 51, Mar. 18, 2014, Figure
21 at 14.
119. Consistent with the evolution of the mobile wireless
marketplace and the Commission's statutory directives and policy goals,
it continues to strive to adopt policies to preserve and promote
consumer choice and competition among multiple service providers,
promote the efficient and intensive use of spectrum, maximize economic
opportunity, and foster the deployment of innovative technologies. For
instance, the Commission recently concluded in the Mobile Spectrum
Holdings Report and Order that any mobile spectrum limit on the initial
licensing of a spectrum band through competitive bidding should be
articulated and applied prior to the start of the auction in order to
provide bidders greater certainty regarding how many licenses they
would be permitted to acquire.
120. In the Mobile Spectrum Holdings Report and Order, the
Commission established a market-based spectrum reserve for the
Incentive Auction of up to 30 megahertz in each license area,
recognizing that the Incentive Auction represents a once-in-a-
generation opportunity to auction significant amounts of greenfield
low-band spectrum. The Commission limited nationwide providers from
bidding on reserved spectrum in Partial Economic Areas (PEAs) where
they hold 45 megahertz or more of suitable and
[[Page 68192]]
available below-1-GHz spectrum. By contrast, the Commission permitted
regional and local service providers to bid on reserved spectrum in all
PEAs, observing that non-nationwide service providers present a
significantly lower risk of effectively denying their rivals access to
low band spectrum to foreclose competition or to raise rivals' costs
because of their relative lack of resources. At the same time, in the
Mobile Spectrum Holdings Report and Order, the Commission placed no
limitation on the amount of spectrum that bidders could acquire in the
AWS-3 auction.
121. In the Mobile Spectrum Holdings Report and Order, the
Commission also stated it would consider in a further notice of
proposed rulemaking possible changes to certain auction rules relating
to joint bidding arrangements and strategies in the Incentive Auction.
The Commission here undertakes a reexamination of its auction rules on
these issues, including but not limited to their application in the
Incentive Auction.
122. Discussion. In light of the changes in the mobile wireless
marketplace since the Commission adopted the current joint bidding
rules 20 years ago, the Commission reviews its rules on joint bidding
and other arrangements to ensure that the potential competitive harms
that may arise out of such arrangements do not outweigh any public
interest benefits. To best serve the public interest and preserve and
promote robust competition into the foreseeable future, the Commission
seeks to further its statutory objectives by adopting policies tailored
to the type of arrangement and its likely competitive effect on the
conduct of the auction and on the mobile wireless marketplace.
Specifically, the Commission tentatively concludes that it would serve
the public interest to retain the current rules governing joint bidding
and other arrangements among non-nationwide providers, but to prohibit
certain joint bidding and other arrangements among nationwide
providers. In addition, the Commission seeks comment on whether the
Commission should revise any of its current rules as applied to
arrangements between nationwide providers and other entities, including
its rules governing short-form applications. Further, the Commission
seeks comment on whether any revisions to its rules governing long-form
applications are necessary in light of its consideration of the
potential harms and benefits of joint bidding and other arrangements.
123. For purposes of this proceeding, the Commission defines
``joint bidding and other arrangements'' to include any bidding
consortia, joint venture, partnership, or agreement, understanding, or
other arrangement entered into relating to the competitive bidding
process, including any agreement relating to post-auction market
structure or operation. In light of the Commission's focus on promoting
and preserving competition, it considers this definition to include not
only arrangements among entities that apply to bid in an auction, but
also arrangements between entities that apply to bid in an auction and
those entities that do not, insofar as such arrangements have the
potential to affect competition in the mobile wireless telephony/mobile
broadband marketplace.
124. Competitive Effects of Joint Bidding and Other Arrangements.
When assessing the competitive effects of joint bidding and other
arrangements, the Commission must ensure that its policies and rules
facilitate access to spectrum in a manner that promotes competition to
the benefit of consumers. As the Commission has found in the Mobile
Spectrum Holdings Report and Order, in order for there to be robust
competition, multiple competing service providers must have access to
or hold sufficient spectrum to be able to enter the marketplace or
expand output rapidly in response to any price increase, reduction in
quality, or other competitive change that would harm consumer welfare.
125. Joint conduct or competitor collaboration that is more limited
in scope and does not result in a full integration of economic activity
does not end all competition between participants post bidding and is
analyzed differently from joint ventures that fully integrate the
participants downstream competition. The latter, in certain
circumstances, may be properly analyzed as a merger. Either type of
competitor collaboration however may result in procompetitive benefits
and/or anticompetitive effects.
126. Because some joint bidding and other competitor collaborations
contemplate competition among participants post auction, they raise the
risk that the spectrum acquired through a winning bid will be allocated
among the joint venture participants in a manner that could harm the
public interest. Because the joint venture may be comprised of same
market competitors, the arrangement may require proper safeguards to
prevent the exchange of competitively sensitive price and output
information, ensure independent decision making or otherwise avoid
lessening competition among the participants in the downstream mobile
wireless marketplace.
127. Joint bidding and other arrangements, however, also have the
potential to result in procompetitive benefits if they enable
participation in auctions by those otherwise without sufficient
financial resources to bid, or otherwise reduce entry costs into a
geographic area or enable the joint bidders to compete more robustly
against other competitors in the marketplace. For example, the pooling
of capital resources could allow smaller providers to better exploit
financial economies of scale and enter into bidding for geographic
areas that otherwise would not have been accessible, which may be
particularly important given the high capital costs of network
deployment and spectrum acquisition.
128. The Commission seeks comment on the foregoing analysis. The
Commission's public interest review of applications for assignment of
licenses through competitive bidding generally encompasses a review of
the competitive effects of such assignments. In light of the changing
marketplace and consistent with the Commission's recent emphasis in the
Mobile Spectrum Holdings proceeding on the need for clearly-defined
rules prior to the auction on the licenses a bidder would be permitted
to acquire, the Commission seeks comment on how best to conduct its
competitive review of joint bidding arrangements going forward.
129. Given the potential benefits and harms of different types of
arrangements, the Commission seeks comment on the rules and procedures
that should govern its review of joint bidding and other arrangements
entered into relating to the competitive bidding process, including any
agreement relating to post-auction market structure or operation. In
addition, the Commission seeks comment on whether the distinctions as
to arrangements among non-nationwide providers, among nationwide
providers, and between nationwide providers and other entities--provide
an effective framework for addressing the relative harms and benefits
of joint bidding arrangements in light of its goal of providing
clearly-defined rules for potential bidders in auctions. Further, the
Commission seeks comment on whether these rules or procedures should
differ in instances in which it has adopted a mobile spectrum holding
limit for the initial licensing of a particular spectrum band through
competitive bidding and, if so, how the type of mobile spectrum holding
limit
[[Page 68193]]
and the statutory goals applicable to the particular auction should
affect these rules and procedures.
130. For purposes of the joint bidding rules, the Commission
proposes to define ``nationwide'' providers to include the providers in
the U.S. with networks that cover a majority of the population and land
area of the country--currently, Verizon Wireless, AT&T, Sprint and T-
Mobile--with other providers being considered ``non-nationwide''
providers. The Commission seeks comment on how this definition of
nationwide providers should take into account entities partially owned
by Verizon Wireless, AT&T, Sprint and T-Mobile. Should the definition
include entities that are ``affiliates'' (as that term is defined in
its rules for attributing revenues to small businesses) of the four
providers, entities with spectrum holdings that would be attributable
to these four providers (as defined by its mobile spectrum holdings
rules), or a category of entities defined in some other manner?
131. Arrangements among Non-Nationwide Providers. Considering the
current competitive landscape and the need for access to spectrum by
non-nationwide providers, the Commission tentatively concludes that its
current rules are sufficient to prevent any potential competitive harm
from outweighing the likely public interest benefits associated with
allowing joint bidding and other arrangements among non-nationwide
providers. For example, joint bidding and other arrangements among non-
nationwide providers can better overcome the challenging capital costs
of license acquisition to maintain or increase their competitive
presence to the benefit of American consumers. In light of the
relatively small size and scope of non-nationwide providers following
substantial consolidation since the Commission's current rules were
adopted, and the increased costs of spectrum and other capital
expenditures necessary to provide mobile broadband service over large
license areas, the Commission believes it is highly unlikely in most
circumstances that such arrangements would lead to competitive harm or
otherwise harm the public interest. Moreover, in the Mobile Spectrum
Holdings Report and Order, the Commission observed that non-nationwide
service providers presented a significantly lower risk of effectively
denying their rivals access to spectrum in order to foreclose
downstream competition or to raise rivals' costs because of their
relative lack of resources. The Commission seeks comment on these views
in connection with the competitive impact of joint bidding and other
arrangements.
132. Commenters proposing any changes to the Commission's joint
bidding rules for arrangements among non-nationwide providers should
discuss why such changes are necessary to address particular
competitive concerns and whether, on balance, such changes would ensure
that the procompetitive benefits and bidding flexibility arising out of
its current rules remain in place. In addition, the Commission seeks
comment on whether any types of arrangements between non-nationwide
service providers and potential new entrants would warrant closer
examination of the competitive effects and, if so, whether any changes
to its joint bidding rules are necessary to address any such scenarios.
133. Arrangements among Nationwide Providers. In contrast, the
Commission tentatively concludes that joint bidding arrangements
between or among nationwide providers likely would raise competitive
concerns, as these arrangements would have the potential to serve as a
vehicle for anticompetitive conduct by altering post auction incentives
to compete, and thus, would outweigh any public interest benefits from
such arrangements such as the attainment of scale or scope economies.
As the Commission noted in the Mobile Spectrum Holdings Report and
Order, the mobile wireless marketplace today is characterized by
factors--such as high market concentration, high margins and high
barriers to entry--that increase the potential for anticompetitive
conduct. In particular, by year end 2013, the top four facilities-based
nationwide providers had a combined market share, as measured by the
number of subscribers or mobile wireless service revenues, of at least
97 percent.
134. Moreover, in light of these factors, joint bidding
arrangements among nationwide providers would reduce the participants'
ability or incentive to compete independently, which would lessen
competition in the downstream mobile wireless marketplace and could
harm American consumers by increasing the price or reducing the quality
of mobile wireless services. Because of these greater risks of public
interest harms, the Commission believes it is unlikely that the
potential benefits of joint bidding arrangements among nationwide
providers would outweigh these risks. The Commission seeks comment on
this analysis.
135. Further, as the Commission has emphasized recently, it is
important to provide bidders with certainty and clarity in advance of
the start of an auction regarding whether any limitations on their
ability to acquire licenses would apply. In that regard, the Commission
observes that post-auction enforcement of antitrust law--envisioned as
a safeguard by the Commission in 1994--may not be as well suited to
preventing anti-competitive joint bidding arrangements as the bright-
line prohibition the Commission proposes herein. In addition, the
Commission notes that, while in 1994 bright-line prohibitions on
certain types of bidding arrangements might not have been ideally
suited for an industry at a nascent stage, the mobile wireless industry
today is much more mature than it was in 1994. Moreover, the limit set
by the Commission at that time on the amount of broadband PCS spectrum
that the two incumbent cellular licensees in each market could acquire
at the auctions effectively eliminated the incentives of those
providers to enter into joint bidding arrangements, which would have
raised significant competitive concerns.
136. Accordingly, the Commission tentatively concludes that it
would best serve the public interest at this time to have a bright-line
rule that would prohibit joint bidding and other arrangements among
nationwide providers, including agreements to participate in an auction
through a newly formed joint entity, given that such arrangements have
a greater potential to harm the public interest by negatively affecting
the competitive bidding process and downstream competition in the
provision of mobile wireless services. The Commission seeks comment on
the costs and benefits of prohibiting applications to participate in an
auction that involve joint bidding and other arrangements, such as a
new joint venture, between two or more nationwide providers. The
Commission notes that its tentative conclusion to prohibit joint
bidding and other arrangements between two nationwide providers would
also include prohibiting arrangements among two nationwide providers,
together with other entities.
137. Arrangements between a Nationwide Provider and Other Entities.
The Commission seeks comment on what policies and procedures should
apply to bidding arrangements between a single nationwide provider and
other entities, either non-nationwide providers or potential new
entrants, in order to promote competition. Under what circumstances
would these arrangements raise competitive concerns? Under what
circumstances
[[Page 68194]]
would these arrangements likely result in public interest benefits,
such as the expansion of mobile wireless services in additional
geographic areas and increasing access to capital by more applicants to
acquire spectrum? Should any limits apply to these types of
arrangements, or should the Commission continue to review these types
of arrangements on a case-by-case basis?
138. If the Commission reviews these types of arrangements on a
case-by-case basis, what process and factors should it use in assessing
the competitive implications? The Commission's current approach for
reviewing joint ventures in the context of assignment or transfer of
licenses involves the determination of the appropriate market
definitions and the likelihood of public interest harm from the
incentive and ability of the joint venture to act anticompetitively,
either unilaterally or in concert with other service providers. Should
a similar approach apply to its competitive review of joint bidding
arrangements? How should a case-by-case approach to review joint
bidding arrangements be designed to provide clarity to potential
bidders? What are the costs and benefits of Commission review of joint
bidding arrangements on a case-by-case basis, including the
administrative cost and burden to make such a case-by-case
determination prior to the start of an auction?
139. To make case-by-case determinations regarding arrangements
between nationwide providers and other entities, should the Commission
modify any of its current rules that apply to the pre-auction review
process? In particular, should the terms and conditions of such joint
bidding arrangements be disclosed prior to the auction, in the short-
form application, or even prior to the filing of that application? If
so, are there changes to its rules or procedures that would be
necessary to protect any confidential information? If the deadline for
disclosure of terms and conditions is in advance of the short-form
application deadline, how would this process be affected by the rules
prohibiting certain types of communications? Commenters on this issue
should include any costs or benefits to changing the rules and
procedures regarding the disclosure of a joint bidding requirement.
140. If the Commission were to make a determination that the
potential harms associated with a particular joint bidding arrangement
outweigh the potential benefits, what remedies should it impose either
at the short-form application stage or the long-form application stage?
For example, should the Commission find that a short-form application
is unacceptable or incomplete and bar the applicant from bidding in the
auction? Should it find that an applicant at the long-form stage is
unqualified to hold the license and deemed in default? Commenters
proposing particular remedies should discuss the costs and benefits of
such remedies.
141. Other Issues. The Commission's current rules require the
entity that filed the short-form application to be the same entity that
files the long-form application seeking consent to acquire a new
license. The Commission's public interest review of long-form
applications generally encompasses a review of the competitive effects
of such assignments, as would its review of a secondary market
transaction to disseminate licenses from a joint entity to its
individual members. The Commission seeks comment on whether it is
necessary to modify its current joint bidding rules, standards, and
procedures that apply to the post-auction review of long-form
applications or review of a secondary market transaction to disseminate
licenses from a joint entity to its individual members, in order to
promote competition in the mobile wireless marketplace.
142. Further, the Commission proposes to clarify a provision under
47 CFR 1.2107(g) which permits DEs to participate in an auction as a
non-legally-recognizable consortium, with a requirement that each
member of the consortium file separate applications for licenses
covered by the winning bids of the consortium. This provision is
applicable only in the DE context, where there are special provisions
regarding the attribution of revenues for purposes of qualifying for
bidding credits. The Commission seeks comment on this clarification.
D. Miscellaneous Part 1 Revisions
143. Background. Part 1, Subpart Q, of the Commission's rules
generally governs competitive bidding proceedings to assign spectrum
licenses. The Commission proposes changes to two of its part 1, Subpart
Q, rules, 47 CFR 1.2111 and 1.2112. The Commission also intends, when
it resolves the issues raised in the Competitive Bidding NPRM, to
resolve long standing petitions for reconsideration to its part 1
competitive bidding rules.
144. Discussion. 47 CFR 1.2111. The Commission proposes to repeal
the first two paragraphs of 47 CFR 1.2111. It proposes to repeal 47 CFR
1.2111(a), under which applicants for assignments or transfers during
the first three years of a license term must provide the Commission
with detailed contract and marketing information. The Commission
believes that this requirement places a burden on licensees without a
corresponding benefit to the Commission or the public. The Commission
also proposes to repeal 47 CFR 1.2111(b), a never-used unjust
enrichment payment requirement for broadband PCS C and F block set-
aside licenses.
145. 47 CFR 1.2112. The Commission's proposed changes to this rule
would clarify the auction application requirements for reporting an
entity's percentage ownership in the applicant and in FCC-regulated
entities. The Commission proposes further changes to specify
application requirements for bidding consortia. Finally, the Commission
proposes to correct two errors in the rule caused by the inadvertent
substitution of an incorrect paragraph in the Code of Federal
Regulations publication of the rule for the correct one published in
the Federal Register summary of the DE Second Report and Order. Compare
71 FR 26245, 26253, May 4, 2006, with 47 CFR 1.2112, Oct. 1, 2006. The
first error was the addition of a requirement that DE short-form
applicants list and summarize all their agreements that support their
DE eligibility, a requirement that the Commission intended to apply
only to long-form applicants. The Commission proposes to delete the
requirement with respect to the short form. The second error was the
deletion of a requirement that DE short-form applicants list the
parties with which they have lease or resale arrangements for any of
the DE applicants' spectrum licenses. The Commission proposes to
reinstate this requirement.
146. The Commission seeks comment on these proposals.
E. Initial Regulatory Flexibility Analysis
147. As required by the Regulatory Flexibility Act of 1980, as
amended (RFA), the Commission has prepared this Initial Regulatory
Flexibility Analysis (IRFA) concerning the possible significant
economic impact on small entities by the policies and rules proposed in
the Competitive Bidding NPRM. Written public comments are requested for
this IRFA. Comments to the IRFA must be identified as responses to the
IRFA and filed by the deadlines for comments on the Competitive Bidding
NPRM in the Dates section. The Commission will send a copy of the
Competitive Bidding NPRM, including the IRFA, to the Chief
[[Page 68195]]
Counsel for Advocacy of the Small Business Administration.
1. Need for, and Objectives of, the Proposed Rules
148. The NPRM proposes to: (1) Provide small businesses greater
opportunity to participate in the provision of a wide range of
spectrum-based services by modifying the Commission's eligibility
requirements, updating the standardized schedule of small business
sizes, and eliminating duplicative reporting requirements, while also
seeking comment on strengthening the Commission's rules to prevent the
unjust enrichment of ineligible entities; (2) Amend the Commission's
former defaulter rule to balance concerns that the current rule is
overly broad with the Commission's continued need to ensure that
auction bidders are financially reliable; (3) Codify an established
competitive bidding procedure that prohibits the same individual or
entity from becoming qualified to bid on the basis of more than one
short-form application in a specific auction; (4) Prevent entities that
are exclusively controlled by a single individual or set of individuals
from becoming qualified to bid on overlapping licenses based on more
than one short-form application in a specific auction; and, (5) Retain
the current rules governing joint bidding arrangements among non-
nationwide providers and prohibit joint bidding arrangements among
nationwide providers. The NPRM also provides notice of the Commission's
intention to resolve long standing petitions for reconsideration and
proposes necessary clean-up revisions to the Commission's part 1
competitive bidding rules.
149. With respect to small businesses, the Commission's proposals
seek to update its rules to reflect that small businesses need greater
opportunities to gain access to capital so that they may have an
opportunity to participate in the provision of spectrum-based services
in today's communications marketplace. In the past decade, the rapid
adoption of smartphones and tablet computers and the widespread use of
mobile applications, combined with the increasing deployment of high-
speed 3G and now 4G technologies, have driven significantly more
intensive use of mobile networks. This progression from the provision
of mobile voice services to the provision of mobile broadband services
has increased the need for access to spectrum. In addition, in the past
decade, the number of small and regional mobile wireless service
providers has significantly decreased, yet regional and local service
providers continue to offer consumers additional choices in the areas
they serve. The Commission anticipates that by revising its rules to
allow small businesses to take advantage of the same opportunities to
utilize their spectrum capacity and gain access to capital as those
afforded to larger licensees, the Commission can better achieve its
statutory directives. Nonetheless, the Commission remains mindful of
its obligation to prevent unjust enrichment of ineligible entities.
2. Description and Estimate of the Number of Small Entities To Which
the Proposed Rules Will Apply
150. The RFA directs the Commission to provide a description of
and, where feasible, an estimate of the number of small entities that
will be affected by the proposed rules, if adopted. The RFA generally
defines the term ``small entity'' as having the same meaning as the
terms ``small business,'' ``small organization,'' and ``small
government jurisdiction.'' In addition, the term ``small business'' has
the same meaning as the term ``small business concern'' under the Small
Business Act. A small business concern is one which: (1) Is
independently owned and operated; (2) is not dominant in its field of
operation; and (3) satisfies any additional criteria established by the
SBA.
151. Small Businesses, Small Organizations, and Small Governmental
Jurisdictions. If adopted, the NPRM's proposals may, over time, affect
small entities that are not easily categorized at present. The
Commission therefore describes three comprehensive, statutory small
entity size standards under 5 U.S.C. 601(4). First, nationwide, there
are a total of approximately 27.5 million small businesses, according
to the SBA. In addition, a ``small organization'' is generally ``any
not-for-profit enterprise which is independently owned and operated and
is not dominant in its field.'' Nationwide, as of 2007, there were
approximately 1,621,315 small organizations. Finally, the term ``small
governmental jurisdiction'' is defined generally as ``governments of
cities, towns, townships, villages, school districts, or special
districts, with a population of less than fifty thousand.'' U.S. Census
Bureau (hereinafter, Census Bureau or Census) data for 2011 indicate
that there were 89,476 local governmental jurisdictions in the United
States. The Commission estimates that, of this total, as many as 88,506
entities may qualify as ``small governmental jurisdictions.'' Thus, the
Commission estimates that most governmental jurisdictions are small.
152. Licenses Assigned by Auction. The changes and additions to the
Commission's rules proposed in the NPRM are of general applicability to
all auctionable services. Accordingly, the IRFA provides a general
analysis of the impact of the proposals on small businesses rather than
a service-by-service analysis. The number of entities that may apply to
participate in future Commission spectrum auctions is unknown.
Moreover, the number of small businesses that have participated in
prior spectrum auctions has varied. As a general matter, the number of
winning bidders that qualify as small businesses at the close of an
auction does not necessarily represent the number of small businesses
currently in service. Also, the Commission does not generally track
subsequent business size unless, in the context of changes in control,
changes in material relationships or assignments or transfers, unjust
enrichment issues are implicated.
153. Wireless Telecommunications Carriers (except satellite). The
Census Bureau defines this category to include establishments engaged
in operating and maintaining switching and transmission facilities to
provide communications via the airwaves. Establishments in this
industry have spectrum licenses and provide services using that
spectrum, such as cellular phone services, paging services, wireless
Internet access, and wireless video services. The SBA has developed a
small business size standard for Wireless Telecommunications Carriers
(except satellite). Under the SBA's standard, a business is small if it
has 1,500 or fewer employees. For this category, Census data for 2007
show that there were 1,383 firms that operated for the entire year. Of
this total, 1,368 firms (approximately 99%) had employment of 999 or
fewer employees and only 15 (approximately 1%) had employment of 1,000
employees or more. Thus under this category and the associated small
business size standard, the Commission estimates that the majority of
wireless telecommunications carriers (except satellite) are small
entities that may be affected by the NPRM's proposed actions.
154. Broadband Radio Service and Educational Broadband Service.
Broadband Radio Service systems, previously referred to as Multipoint
Distribution Service (MDS) and Multichannel Multipoint Distribution
Service (MMDS) systems, and ``wireless cable,'' transmit video
programming to subscribers and provide two-way high speed data
operations using the microwave frequencies of the
[[Page 68196]]
Broadband Radio Service (BRS) and Educational Broadband Service (EBS)
(previously referred to as the Instructional Television Fixed Service
(ITFS)). In connection with the 1996 BRS auction, the Commission
established a small business size standard as an entity that had annual
average gross revenues of no more than $40 million in the previous
three calendar years. The BRS auction resulted in 67 successful bidders
obtaining licensing opportunities for 493 Basic Trading Areas (BTAs).
Of the 67 auction winners, 61 met the definition of a small business.
BRS also includes licensees of stations authorized prior to the
auction. At this time, based on the Commission's review of licensing
records, it estimates that of the 61 small business BRS auction
winners, 48 remain small business licensees. In addition to the 48
small businesses that hold BTA authorizations, there are approximately
86 incumbent BRS licensees that are considered small entities (18
incumbent BRS licensees do not meet the small business size standard).
After adding the number of small business auction licensees to the
number of incumbent licensees not already counted, there are currently
approximately 133 BRS licensees that are defined as small businesses
under either the SBA or the Commission's rules. In 2009, the Commission
conducted Auction 86, the sale of 78 licenses in the BRS areas. The
Commission established three small business size standards that were
used in Auction 86: (i) An entity with attributed average annual gross
revenues that exceeded $15 million and do not exceed $40 million for
the preceding three years was considered a small business; (ii) an
entity with attributed average annual gross revenues that exceeded $3
million and did not exceed $15 million for the preceding three years
was considered a very small business; and (iii) an entity with
attributed average annual gross revenues that did not exceed $3 million
for the preceding three years was considered an entrepreneur. Auction
86 concluded in 2009 with the sale of 61 licenses. Of the 10 winning
bidders, two bidders that claimed small business status won four
licenses; one bidder that claimed very small business status won three
licenses; and two bidders that claimed entrepreneur status won six
licenses. The Commission notes that, as a general matter, the number of
winning bidders that qualify as small businesses at the close of an
auction does not necessarily represent the number of small businesses
currently in service.
155. In addition, the SBA's placement of Cable Television
Distribution Services in the category of Wired Telecommunications
Carriers is applicable to cable-based educational broadcasting
services. Since 2007, the Census Bureau has defined Wired
Telecommunications Carriers as follows: ``This industry comprises [of]
establishments primarily engaged in operating and/or providing access
to transmission facilities and infrastructure that they own and/or
lease for the transmission of voice, data, text, sound, and video using
wired telecommunications networks. Transmission facilities may be based
on a single technology or a combination of technologies.''
Establishments in this industry use the wired telecommunications
network facilities that they operate to provide a variety of services,
such as wired telephony services, including VoIP services; wired
(cable) audio and video programming distribution; and wired broadband
Internet services. By exception, establishments providing satellite
television distribution services using facilities and infrastructure
that they operate are included in this industry. The SBA has developed
a small business size standard for this category, which is: All such
firms having 1,500 or fewer employees. Census data for 2007 shows that
there were 3,188 firms that operated for the duration of that year. Of
those, 3,144 had fewer than 1,000 employees, and 44 firms had more than
1,000 employees. Thus under this category and the associated small
business size standard, the majority of such firms can be considered
small. In addition to Census data, the Commission's Universal Licensing
System indicates that as of July 2014, there are 2,006 active EBS
licenses. The Commission estimates that of these 2,006 licenses, the
majority are held by non-profit educational institutions and school
districts, which are by statute defined as small businesses.
156. Television Broadcasting. As defined by the Census Bureau, this
category ``comprises [of] establishments primarily engaged in
broadcasting images together with sound. These establishments operate
television broadcasting studios and facilities for the programming and
transmission of programs to the public.'' The SBA has created the
following small business size standard for Television Broadcasting
firms: those having $38.5 million or less in annual receipts. The
Commission has estimated the number of licensed commercial television
stations to be 1,387. In addition, according to Commission staff review
of the BIA/Kelsey, LLC's Media Access Pro Television Database on July
30, 2014, about 1,276 of an estimated 1,387 commercial television
stations (or approximately 92 percent) had revenues of $38.5 million or
less. The Commission therefore estimates that the majority of
commercial television broadcasters are small entities.
157. The Commission notes, however, that in assessing whether a
business concern qualifies as small, business (control) affiliations
must be included. The Commission's estimates, therefore, likely
overstates the number of small entities that might be affected by the
NPRM's proposals because the revenue figure on which it is based does
not include or aggregate revenues from affiliated companies. In
addition, an element of the definition of ``small business'' is that
the entity not be dominant in its field of operation. The Commission is
unable at this time to define or quantify the criteria that would
establish whether a specific television station is dominant in its
field of operation. Accordingly, the estimate of small businesses to
which rules may apply does not exclude any television station from the
definition of a small business on this basis and is therefore possibly
over-inclusive to that extent.
158. In addition, the Commission has estimated the number of
licensed noncommercial educational (NCE) television stations to be 395.
These stations are non-profit, and therefore considered to be small
entities.
159. There are also 2,460 LPTV stations, including Class A
stations, and 3,838 TV translator stations. Given the nature of these
services, the Commission will presume that all of these entities
qualify as small entities under the above SBA small business size
standard.
160. Radio Broadcasting. The SBA defines a radio broadcast station
as a small business if such station has no more than $38.5 million in
annual receipts. As defined by the Census Bureau, business concerns in
this industry are those ``primarily engaged in broadcasting aural
programs by radio to the public.'' According to review of the BIA/
Kelsey, LLC's Media Access Pro Radio Database as of July 30, 2014,
about 11,332 (or about 99.9 percent) of 11,343 commercial radio
stations have revenues of $38.5 million or less and thus qualify as
small entities under the SBA definition. The Commission notes, however,
that, in assessing whether a business concern qualifies as small,
business (control) affiliations must be included. This estimate,
therefore, likely overstates the number of small entities
[[Page 68197]]
that might be affected, because the revenue figure on which it is based
does not include or aggregate revenues from affiliated companies.
161. In addition, an element of the definition of ``small
business'' is that the entity not be dominant in its field of
operation. The Commission is unable at this time to define or quantify
the criteria that would establish whether a specific radio station is
dominant in its field of operation. Accordingly, the estimate of small
businesses to which rules may apply does not exclude any radio station
from the definition of a small business on this basis and therefore may
be over-inclusive to that extent. Also, as noted, an additional element
of the definition of ``small business'' is that the entity must be
independently owned and operated. The Commission notes that it is
difficult at times to assess these criteria in the context of media
entities and the estimates of small businesses to which they apply may
be over-inclusive to this extent.
3. Description of Projected Reporting, Recordkeeping, and Other
Compliance Requirements for Small Entities
162. Eligibility for Bidding Credits. The NPRM proposes changes to
the Commission's process for evaluating small business eligibility for
bidding credits. In particular, the NPRM proposes to repeal the AMR
rule and tentatively concludes that the Commission should re-examine
the need for the related decade-old policy that has limited small
businesses seeking bidding credits to providing primarily retail,
facilities-based service directly to the public with each of their
licenses. Under the AMR, a small business applicant or licensee must
automatically attribute to itself the gross revenues of any entity with
which it has an ``attributable material relationship.'' An applicant or
licensee has an AMR when it has one or more agreements with any
individual entity for the lease (under either spectrum manager or de
facto transfer leasing arrangements) or resale (including under a
wholesale arrangement) of, on a cumulative basis, more than 25 percent
of the spectrum capacity of any individual license held by the
applicant or licensee. The NPRM seeks comment on the proposal to repeal
the AMR rule, and the Commission's tentative conclusions regarding its
need to re-evaluate its small business policy. Alternatively, the NPRM
also seeks comment on retaining the Commission's small business policy
and/or some variation of the AMR rule. For instance, the NPRM seeks
comment on whether the Commission should adopt a rule with some other
spectrum capacity use limit that would render an applicant ineligible
for all current and future benefits.
163. The NPRM also proposes to adopt a more flexible approach under
which the Commission would evaluate small business eligibility on a
license-by-license basis, using a two-pronged test. The first prong
would evaluate whether an applicant meets the applicable small business
size standard and is therefore eligible for benefits. To evaluate small
business eligibility, the NPRM proposes to apply the Commission's
existing controlling interest standard and affiliation rules to
determine whether, an entity should be attributable based on whether
that entity has de jure or de facto control of, or is affiliated with,
the applicant's overall business venture. Once the first prong has been
met, the Commission would evaluate eligibility under the second prong.
Under the second prong, the NPRM proposes to determine an entity's
eligibility to retain small business benefits on a license-by-license
basis, based on whether it has maintained de jure and de facto control
of the license. Under this proposed license-by-license approach, an
entity will not necessarily lose its eligibility for all current and
future small business benefits solely because of a decision associated
with any particular license. Instead, while a small business might
incur unjust enrichment obligations if it relinquishes de jure or de
facto control of any particular license for which it claimed benefits,
so long as the revenues of its attributable interest holders (i.e., the
DE's affiliates, its controlling interests, and the affiliates of its
controlling interests) continue to qualify under the relevant small
business size standard, it could still retain its eligibility to retain
current and future benefits on existing and future licenses. The NPRM
seeks comment on the proposed two-pronged approach to evaluate
attribution and establish eligibility for small business benefits.
164. The NPRM also proposes to modify the Commission's secondary
market rules to comport with the Commission's proposed approach to
assessing small business eligibility. Specifically, the NPRM proposes
to modify the language in 47 CFR 1.9020(d)(4) to remove the conflicting
reference to the control standard of 47 CFR 1.2110 in order to make
clear that small business lessors are fully subject to the same de
facto control standard for spectrum manager leasing that applies to all
other licensees. This modification should clarify that 47 CFR 1.9010
alone defines whether a licensee, including a small business, retains
de facto control of the spectrum that it leases to a spectrum lessee in
the context of spectrum manager leasing.
165. The NPRM seeks comment on whether any changes are appropriate
to the Commission's unjust enrichment rules that provide additional
safeguards by requiring repayment of small business benefits where an
applicant loses eligibility for any reason. Specifically, the NPRM
invites comment on, among other things, whether to adjust the
Commission's current five year unjust enrichment schedule either in
terms of the duration of the requirements or the percentages of the
repayment schedule. The NPRM also seeks comment on how best the
Commission can continue to scrutinize applications and proposed
transactions to ensure that only eligible entities receive benefits,
while not undermining the Act's directive to ensure that DEs are given
the opportunity to participate in the provision of spectrum-based
services. Specifically, the NPRM seeks comment on adopting a 10 year
unjust enrichment repayment schedule similar to the one it adopted in
2006, but vacated by the Third Circuit for lack of notice.
166. Bidding Credits. The NPRM examines the primary way that the
Commission facilitates participation by small businesses at auction
through its bidding credit program. Bidding credits operate as a
percentage discount on the winning bid amounts of a qualifying small
business. By making the acquisition of spectrum licenses more
affordable for new and existing small businesses, bidding credits
facilitate their access to needed capital. The Commission establishes
eligibility for bidding credits for each auctionable service, adopting
one or more definitions of the small businesses that will be eligible.
The Commission's small business definitions have been based on an
applicant's average annual gross revenues over a three-year period. The
NPRM proposes to increase the general schedule of size standards in its
part 1 rules, measured by gross revenues, for purposes of determining
an entity's eligibility for a bidding preference. Specifically, the
NPRM proposes to revise the standardized schedule in 47 CFR 1.2110(f)
as follows: (1) Businesses with average annual gross revenues for the
preceding three years not exceeding $4 million would be eligible for a
35 percent bidding credit; (2) Businesses with average annual gross
revenues for the preceding three years not exceeding $20 million would
be eligible for a 25 percent bidding credit; and (3) Businesses with
average annual gross
[[Page 68198]]
revenues for the preceding three years not exceeding $55 million would
be eligible for a 15 percent bidding credit. The NPRM also asks about
alternative methods for setting new gross revenues thresholds.
167. The NPRM seeks comment on whether to adopt a small business
size standard based on criteria other than gross revenues, and proposes
to continue the Commission's practice of evaluating which small
business definitions will apply on a service-by-service basis, based
upon associated capital requirements for a particular service. In
addition, the NPRM seeks comment on whether to increase the bidding
credit percentages (i.e., discount amounts) applicable to associated
small business categories. The NPRM also seeks comment on whether any
revisions the Commission adopts in this proceeding to its part 1
schedule of small business size standards and associated bidding credit
percentage levels should apply to the specific small business
definitions and bidding credit percentages the Commission previously
adopted for specific services, and, if so, how such revisions would be
implemented. The NPRM proposes that any new rules adopted in this
proceeding would apply to the 600 MHz band spectrum licenses to be
offered in the BIA. In the BIA proceeding, the Commission adopted a 15
percent bidding credit for small businesses (defined as entities with
average annual gross revenues for the preceding three years not
exceeding $40 million) and a 25 percent bidding credit for very small
businesses (defined as entities with average annual gross revenues for
the preceding three years not exceeding $15 million). Accordingly, the
NPRM proposes to adopt, for the 600 MHz band, increases in the gross
revenues thresholds associated with the 25 percent and 15 percent
bidding credits that are consistent with the increased gross revenues
thresholds proposed in the NPRM for the standardized schedule in the
Commission's part 1 competitive bidding rules. The NPRM also seeks
comment on whether the Commission should adopt a third small business
bidding credit tier for the 600 MHz band that would provide a 35
percent bidding credit to businesses with average gross revenues for
the preceding three years not exceeding $4 million.
168. Further, the NPRM seeks comment on the Commission's ability to
consider bidding preferences for other types of DEs, entities that
serve unserved/underserved areas or areas with persistent poverty, as
well as persons or entities that have overcome disadvantages. The NPRM
asks commenters to specifically address the statutory authority and
judicial scrutiny issues that may limit the Commission's ability to
entertain recommendations to alter the focus of its current bidding
preferences by offering bidding preferences to entities based on other
criteria than business size.
169. The Commission expects that the questions raised in the NPRM
will provide a meaningful opportunity to evaluate whether its bidding
credit program continues to achieve the Commission's objectives. To
facilitate the Commission's review, the NPRM seeks concrete, specific,
data-driven feedback by commenters. In addition, the NPRM invites
commenters to suggest other creative ideas that would promote the
Commission's statutory objectives, but emphasizes that for any such
proposals it is imperative to provide ample supporting evidence.
170. DE Reporting Requirements. The NPRM proposes to eliminate the
DE annual reporting requirement in 47 CFR 1.2110(n) and questions
whether the value of the information provided in those reports
outweighs the regulatory burden that the reporting obligation places on
small businesses. The NPRM seeks comment on this proposal. Among other
things, the NPRM asks if the Commission adopts the proposal to
eliminate this annual reporting requirement, whether it should amend
its rule for reporting eligibility events to require that a small
business must list and summarize all existing agreements to provide
context each time it reports a new eligibility event.
171. MMTC White Paper Requests. In February 2014, MMTC submitted a
White Paper detailing several policy recommendations to advance
licensing of spectrum to minority- and women-owned businesses. The NPRM
raises and addresses several of these issues and seeks comments on the
other proposals that are not otherwise addressed in the NPRM, and to
the extent that they relate to the Commission's competitive bidding
rules. The NPRM observes that certain proposals appear to be outside
the scope of this proceeding and others may not be needed in light of
other changes proposed in the NPRM. Toward that end, the NPRM
tentatively concludes that the following MMTC proposals are outside the
scope of this proceeding, which is focused on the Commission's
competitive bidding rules, and thus will not be addressed in the NPRM:
(1) Incorporating diversity and inclusion in the Commission's public
interest analysis of mergers and acquisitions and secondary market
spectrum transactions; and (2) supporting increased funding for and
statutory amendments regarding the Telecommunications Development Fund.
172. Former Defaulter Rule. The NPRM proposes changes to the
Commission's former defaulter rule to balance concerns that the current
rule is overly broad with the Commission's continued need to ensure
that auction bidders are financially reliable. The NPRM seeks comment
on revising the rule to narrow the scope of the defaults and
delinquencies that will be considered in determining whether or not an
auction participant is a former defaulter. Specifically, the NPRM
proposes to exclude any cured default on any Commission license or
delinquency on any non-tax debt owed to any federal agency for which
any of the following criteria are met: (1) The notice of the final
payment deadline or delinquency was received more than seven years
before the relevant short-form application deadline; (2) the default or
delinquency amounted to less than $100,000; (3) the default or
delinquency was paid within two quarters (i.e., 6 months) after
receiving the notice of the final payment deadline or delinquency; or
(4) the default or delinquency was the subject of a legal or
arbitration proceeding that was cured upon resolution of the
proceeding. Additionally, the NPRM seeks comment on limiting the
individuals and entities that an applicant must consider when
determining its status as a former defaulter.
173. Commonly Controlled Entities. The NPRM proposes to codify an
established competitive bidding procedure that prohibits the same
individual or entity from filing more than one short-form application
to participate in an auction. The NPRM also proposes a new rule that
would prevent entities that are exclusively controlled by a single
individual or set of individuals from qualifying to bid on licenses in
the same or overlapping geographic areas in a specific auction on more
than one short-form application. These proposals seek to improve the
transparency and efficiency of the auction process, by making clearer
who the qualified bidders actually are and ensuring against the
potential for anticompetitive auction behavior. The NPRM seeks comment
on these proposals and on specific alternatives to address the
Commission's concern that common control may allow the controlling
individual or set of individuals to attempt to gain advantages in the
bidding process based
[[Page 68199]]
on certain coordinated bidding actions (e.g., tied bids, activity
waivers).
174. Joint Bidding. The NPRM initiates a review of the Commission's
rules and policies governing joint bidding and other arrangements in
order to ensure that they fulfill the Commission's statutory
objectives, given the changes in the mobile wireless marketplace since
the initial adoption of the bidding rules two decades ago, and the
increasing importance of spectrum for service providers to meet
consumer demand for mobile wireless services. The NPRM seeks comment on
the Commission's tentative conclusions that it would be in the public
interest to retain the current rules governing joint bidding
arrangements among non-nationwide providers and to prohibit joint
bidding arrangements among nationwide providers. Additionally, the NPRM
seeks comment on whether the Commission should revise any of its
current rules as applied to arrangements between nationwide providers
and other entities, including its rules governing short-form
applications. Further, the NPRM seeks comment on whether any revisions
to the Commission's rules governing long-form applications are
necessary in light of the Commission's consideration of the potential
harms and benefits of joint bidding and other arrangements.
175. Miscellaneous Part 1 Revisions. In addition to changes that
would implement the foregoing proposals, the NPRM proposes changes to
two of the Commission's part 1, Subpart Q, rules, 47 CFR 1.2111 and
1.2112. 47 CFR 1.2111--The NPRM proposes to eliminate two provisions of
this rule: (1) 47 CFR 1.2111(a), under which applicants for assignments
or transfers during the first three years of a license term must
provide the Commission with detailed contract and marketing
information, and (2) 47 CFR 1.2111(b), a never-used unjust enrichment
payment requirement for broadband PCS C and F block set-aside licenses.
47 CFR 1.2112--The NPRM's proposed changes to this rule clarify the
auction application requirements for reporting an entity's percentage
ownership in the applicant and in FCC-regulated entities. The NPRM
proposes further changes to specify application requirements for
bidding consortia. The NPRM also proposes to correct two errors in the
rule caused by the inadvertent substitution of an incorrect paragraph
in the Code of Federal Regulations publication of the rule for the
correct one published in the Federal Register summary of the DE Second
Report and Order. The first error was the addition of a requirement
that DE short-form applicants list and summarize all their agreements
that support their DE eligibility, a requirement that the Commission
intended to apply only to long-form applicants. The NPRM proposes to
delete the requirement with respect to the short-form. The second error
was the deletion of a requirement that DE short-form applicants list
the parties with which they have lease or resale arrangements for any
of the DE applicants' spectrum. The NPRM proposes to reinstate this
requirement.
176. The NPRM seeks comments on these proposals. In addition, the
NPRM notes that the Commission intends, when it resolves the issues
raised in the NPRM, to resolve long standing petitions for
reconsideration to the Commission's part 1 competitive bidding rules.
4. Steps Taken To Minimize Significant Economic Impact on Small
Entities, and Significant Alternatives Considered
177. The RFA requires an agency to describe any significant
alternatives that it has considered in reaching its proposed approach,
which may include the following four alternatives (among others): (1)
The establishment of differing compliance or reporting requirements or
timetables that take into account the resources available to small
entities; (2) the clarification, consolidation, or simplification of
compliance or reporting requirements under the rule for small entities;
(3) the use of performance, rather than design, standards; and (4) an
exemption from coverage of the rule, or any part thereof, for small
entities.
178. If adopted, the NPRM's proposed approach to evaluating
attribution and establishing small business eligibility could provide
small businesses with greater opportunities to participate in the
provision of spectrum-based services. Moreover, insofar as the NPRM's
proposals should allow small businesses greater flexibility to engage
in business ventures that include increased forms of leasing and other
spectrum use arrangements, the Commission anticipates that the combined
intent of the proposals should increase the potential sources of
revenue for the small business and decrease the likelihood that it
would be subject to undue influence by any particular user of a single
license. The NPRM's proposed two-pronged approach to establishing small
business eligibility would also ensure that a licensee retains control
of all licenses for which it seeks bidding credits, while providing
greater flexibility for any acquired without such benefits. Further,
the proposal to eliminate the AMR rule and to clarify how spectrum
manager leasing rules apply to DEs should allow small businesses
greater certainty to participate in secondary markets transactions.
179. The NPRM's proposed increases in the gross revenues thresholds
that define the three tiers of small businesses in the part 1 schedule
by which the Commission provides the corresponding available bidding
credits would encourage small business participation in spectrum
license auctions. The proposed gross revenues thresholds are intended
to more accurately reflect what constitutes a ``small business'' in
today's marketplace, taking into consideration the relative size of the
large, national providers. This proposal will provide an economic
benefit to small entities by making it easier to acquire spectrum
licenses. Moreover, the NPRM's proposal to repeal the DE reporting
requirement would eliminate the burden on DEs to submit annual reports.
180. The proposed changes to the part 1 rules will apply to all
entities in the same manner the Commission will apply these changes
uniformly to all entities that choose to participate in spectrum
license auctions. The Commission believes that applying the same rules
equally to all entities in these contexts promotes fairness. The
Commission does not believe that the limited costs and/or
administrative burdens associated with the rule revisions will unduly
burden small entities. In fact, many of the proposed rule revisions
clarify the Commission's competitive bidding rules, including short-
form application requirements, as well as reduce reporting
requirements.
181. Finally, the NPRM's joint bidding proposals are intended to
preserve and promote robust competition in the mobile wireless
marketplace and facilitate competition among bidders at auction,
including small entities. These proposals provide potential bidders
with greater clarity regarding the types of joint bidding arrangements
that would be permissible. In addition, the NPRM's proposal to retain
its current rules for joint bidding arrangements among non-nationwide
providers would maintain flexibility for small businesses to enter into
such arrangements.
List of Subjects
47 CFR Part 1
Administrative practice and procedure.
47 CFR Part 27
Communications common carriers, Radio.
[[Page 68200]]
Federal Communications Commission.
Marlene H. Dortch,
Secretary.
Proposed Rules
For the reasons discussed in the preamble, the Federal
Communications Commission proposes to amend 47 CFR Parts 1 and 27 as
follows:
PART 1--PRACTICE AND PROCEDURE
0
1. The authority citation for part 1 continues to read as follows:
Authority: 15 U.S.C. 79 et seq.; 47 U.S.C. 151, 154(i), 154(j),
155, 157, 225, 227, 303(r), 309, 1403, 1404, 1451, and 1452.
0
2. Section 1.2105 is amended by revising paragraphs (a)(2)(xi) and
(b)(1) to read as follows:
Sec. 1.2105 Bidding application and certification procedures;
prohibition of certain communications.
* * * * *
(a) * * *
(2) * * *
(xi) An attached statement made under penalty of perjury indicating
whether or not the applicant has been in default on any Commission
license or has been delinquent on any non-tax debt owed to any Federal
agency. For purposes of this certification, an applicant may exclude
from consideration as a former default any default on a Commission
license or delinquency on non-tax debt to any Federal agency that has
been resolved and meets any of the following criteria:
(A) The notice of the final payment deadline or delinquency was
received more than seven years before the short-form application
deadline;
(B) The default or delinquency amounted to less than $100,000;
(C) The default or delinquency was paid within two quarters (i.e.,
6 months) after receiving the notice of the final payment deadline or
delinquency; or
(D) The default or delinquency was the subject of a legal or
arbitration proceeding that was cured upon resolution of the
proceeding.
* * * * *
(b) Modification and Dismissal of Short-Form Application (FCC Form
175).
(1)(i) Any short-form application (FCC Form 175) that does not
contain all of the certifications required pursuant to this section is
unacceptable for filing and cannot be corrected subsequent to the
applicable filing deadline. The application will be deemed incomplete,
the applicant will not be found qualified to bid, and the upfront
payment, if paid, will be returned.
(ii) If (A) An individual or entity submits multiple applications
in a single auction; or
(B) Entities commonly controlled by the same individual or same set
of individuals submit applications for any set of licenses in the same
or overlapping geographic areas in a single auction; then only one of
such applications may be deemed complete, and the other such
application(s) will be deemed incomplete, such applicants will not be
found qualified to bid, and the associated upfront payment(s), if paid,
will be returned.
* * * * *
0
3. Section 1.2106 is amended by revising paragraph (a) to read as
follows:
Sec. 1.2106 Submission of upfront payments.
(a) The Commission may require applicants for licenses subject to
competitive bidding to submit an upfront payment. In that event, the
amount of the upfront payment and the procedures for submitting it will
be set forth in a Public Notice. Any auction applicant that, pursuant
to Sec. 1.2105(a)(2)(xi), certifies that it is a former defaulter must
submit an upfront payment equal to 50 percent more than that set for
each particular license. No interest will be paid on upfront payments.
* * * * *
0
4. Amend Sec. 1.2110 as follows:
0
A. Revise paragraph (b)(1)(i) and (ii);
0
B. Remove paragraph (b)(3)(iv);
0
C. Revise paragraphs (f)(2) and (j);
0
D. Remove paragraph (n);
0
E. Redesignate paragraphs (o) and (p) as paragraphs (n) and (o)
The additions and revisions read as follows:
Sec. 1.2110 Designated entities.
* * * * *
(b) * * *
(1) * * *
(i) The gross revenues of the applicant (or licensee), its
affiliates, its controlling interests, and the affiliates of its
controlling interests shall be attributed to the applicant (or
licensee) and considered on a cumulative basis and aggregated for
purposes of determining whether the applicant (or licensee) is eligible
for status as a small business, very small business, or entrepreneur,
as those terms are defined in the service-specific rules. An applicant
seeking status as a small business, very small business, or
entrepreneur, as those terms are defined in the service-specific rules,
must disclose on its short- and long-form applications, separately and
in the aggregate, the gross revenues for each of the previous three
years of the applicant (or licensee), its affiliates, its controlling
interests, and the affiliates of its controlling interests.
(ii) If applicable, pursuant to Sec. 24.709 of this chapter, the
total assets of the applicant (or licensee), its affiliates, its
controlling interests, and the affiliates of its controlling interests
shall be attributed to the applicant (or licensee) and considered on a
cumulative basis and aggregated for purposes of determining whether the
applicant (or licensee) is eligible for status as an entrepreneur. An
applicant seeking status as an entrepreneur must disclose on its short-
and long-form applications, separately and in the aggregate, the gross
revenues for each of the previous two years of the applicant (or
licensee), its affiliates, its controlling interests, and the
affiliates of its controlling interests.
* * * * *
(f) * * *
(2) Size of bidding credits. A winning bidder that qualifies as a
small business may use the following bidding credits corresponding to
its respective average gross revenues for the preceding 3 years:
(i) Businesses with average gross revenues for the preceding 3
years not exceeding $4 million are eligible for bidding credits of 35
percent;
(ii) Businesses with average gross revenues for the preceding 3
years not exceeding $20 million are eligible for bidding credits of 25
percent; and
(iii) Businesses with average gross revenues for the preceding 3
years not exceeding $55 million are eligible for bidding credits of 15
percent.
* * * * *
(j) Designated entities must describe on their long-form
applications how they satisfy the requirements for eligibility for
designated entity status, and must list and summarize on their long
form applications all agreements that affect designated entity status
such as partnership agreements, shareholder agreements, management
agreements, spectrum leasing arrangements, spectrum resale (including
wholesale) arrangements, and all other agreements including oral
agreements, establishing as applicable, de facto or de jure control of
the entity. Designated entities also must provide the date(s) on which
they entered into of the agreements listed. In addition, designated
entities must file with their long-form applications a copy of each
such agreement. In order to enable the Commission to audit designated
entity eligibility on an ongoing basis, designated entities that are
awarded eligibility must, for the term of the license, maintain at
their facilities or with their designated agents the lists, summaries,
dates and copies of
[[Page 68201]]
agreements required to be identified and provided to the Commission
pursuant to this paragraph and to Sec. 1.2114.
* * * * *
0
5. Section 1.2111 is revised to read as follows:
Sec. 1.2111 Assignment or transfer of control: unnjust enrichment.
(a) Unjust enrichment payment: installment financing.
(1) If a licensee that utilizes installment financing under this
section seeks to assign or transfer control of its license to an entity
not meeting the eligibility standards for installment payments, the
licensee must make full payment of the remaining unpaid principal and
any unpaid interest accrued through the date of assignment or transfer
as a condition of approval.
(2) If a licensee that utilizes installment financing under this
section seeks to make any change in ownership structure that would
result in the licensee's losing eligibility for installment payments,
the licensee shall first seek Commission approval and must make full
payment of the remaining unpaid principal and any unpaid interest
accrued through the date of such change as a condition of approval. A
licensee's (or other attributable entity's) increased gross revenues or
increased total assets due to nonattributable equity investments, debt
financing, revenue from operations or other investments, business
development or expanded service shall not be considered to result in
the licensee losing eligibility for installment payments.
(3) If a licensee seeks to make any change in ownership that would
result in the licensee's qualifying for a less favorable installment
plan under this section, the licensee shall seek Commission approval
and must adjust its payment plan to reflect its new eligibility status.
A licensee may not switch its payment plan to a more favorable plan.
(b) Unjust enrichment payment: bidding credits.
(1) A licensee that utilizes a bidding credit, and that during the
initial term seeks to assign or transfer control of a license to an
entity that does not meet the eligibility criteria for a bidding
credit, will be required to reimburse the U.S. Government for the
amount of the bidding credit, plus interest based on the rate for ten
year U.S. Treasury obligations applicable on the date the license was
granted, as a condition of Commission approval of the assignment or
transfer. If, within the initial term of the license, a licensee that
utilizes a bidding credit seeks to assign or transfer control of a
license to an entity that is eligible for a lower bidding credit, the
difference between the bidding credit obtained by the assigning party
and the bidding credit for which the acquiring party would qualify,
plus interest based on the rate for ten year U.S. treasury obligations
applicable on the date the license is granted, must be paid to the U.S.
Government as a condition of Commission approval of the assignment or
transfer. If, within the initial term of the license, a licensee that
utilizes a bidding credit makes any ownership change or enters into any
agreement that would result in the licensee's losing eligibility for a
bidding credit (or qualifying for a lower bidding credit), the amount
of the bidding credit (or the difference between the bidding credit
originally obtained and the bidding credit for which the licensee would
qualify after restructuring or under the agreement), plus interest
based on the rate for ten year U.S. treasury obligations applicable on
the date the license is granted, must be paid to the U.S. Government as
a condition of Commission approval of the assignment or transfer or of
a reportable eligibility event (see Sec. 1.2114).
(2) Payment schedule.
(i) The amount of payments made pursuant to paragraph (b)(1) of
this section will be reduced over time as follows:
(A) A loss of eligibility in the first two years of the license
term will result in a forfeiture of 100 percent of the value of the
bidding credit (or in the case of very small businesses transferring to
small businesses, 100 percent of the difference between the bidding
credit received by the former and the bidding credit for which the
latter is eligible);
(B) A loss of eligibility in year 3 of the license term will result
in a forfeiture of 75 percent of the value of the bidding credit (or in
the case of eligibility changing to qualify for a lower bidding credit,
75 percent of the difference between the bidding credit received and
the bidding credit for which it is eligible);
(C) A loss of eligibility in year 4 of the license term will result
in a forfeiture of 50 percent of the value of the bidding credit (or in
the case of eligibility changing to qualify for a lower bidding credit,
50 percent of the difference between the bidding credit received and
the bidding credit for which it is eligible);
(D) A loss of eligibility in year 5 of the license term will result
in a forfeiture of 25 percent of the value of the bidding credit (or in
the case of eligibility changing to qualify for a lower bidding credit,
25 percent of the difference between the bidding credit received and
the bidding credit for which it is eligible); and
(E) For a loss of eligibility in year 6 or thereafter, there will
be no payment.
(ii) These payments will have to be paid to the United States
Treasury as a condition of approval of the assignment, transfer,
ownership change or reportable eligibility event (see Sec. 1.2114).
(c) Unjust enrichment: partitioning and disaggregation--
(1) Installment payments. Licensees making installment payments,
that partition their licenses or disaggregate their spectrum to
entities not meeting the eligibility standards for installment
payments, will be subject to the provisions concerning unjust
enrichment as set forth in this section.
(2) Bidding credits. Licensees that received a bidding credit that
partition their licenses or disaggregate their spectrum to entities not
meeting the eligibility standards for such a bidding credit, will be
subject to the provisions concerning unjust enrichment as set forth in
this section.
(3) Apportioning unjust enrichment payments. Unjust enrichment
payments for partitioned license areas shall be calculated based upon
the ratio of the population of the partitioned license area to the
overall population of the license area and by utilizing the most recent
Census data. Unjust enrichment payments for disaggregated spectrum
shall be calculated based upon the ratio of the amount of spectrum
disaggregated to the amount of spectrum held by the licensee.
0
6. Section 1.2112 is amended by revising paragraphs (a)(7), (b)(1)(iii)
and (iv); adding paragraph (b)(1)(v); and revising paragraph
(b)(2)(ii), (iii) and (v) to read as follows:
Sec. 1.2112 Ownership disclosure requirements for applications.
(a) * * *
(7) List any FCC-regulated entity or applicant for an FCC license,
in which the applicant or any of the parties identified in paragraphs
(a)(1) through (a)(5) of this section holds a 10 percent or greater
ownership interest, regardless of the type of business entity,
including both active and passive interests. This list must include a
description of each such entity's principal business and a description
of each such entity's relationship to the applicant (e.g., Company A
owns 10 percent of Company B (the applicant) and 10 percent of Company
C, then Companies A and C must be listed on Company B's application,
where C is an FCC licensee and/or license applicant).
(b) * * *
[[Page 68202]]
(1) * * *
(iii) List all parties with which the applicant has entered into
arrangements for the spectrum lease or resale (including wholesale
arrangements) of any of the capacity of any of the applicant's
spectrum.
(iv) List separately and in the aggregate the gross revenues,
computed in accordance with Sec. 1.2110, for each of the following:
The applicant, its affiliates, its controlling interests, and the
affiliates of its controlling interests; and if a consortium of small
businesses, the members comprising the consortium.
(v) If applying as a consortium under Sec. 1.2110(b)(3)(i),
provide the information in paragraphs (b)(1)(i) through (iv) separately
for each member of the consortium.
(2) * * *
(ii) List any FCC-regulated entity or applicant for an FCC license,
in which any controlling interest of the applicant owns a 10 percent or
greater interest or a total of 10 percent or more of any class of
stock, warrants, options or debt securities. This list must include a
description of each such entity's principal business and a description
of each such entity's relationship to the applicant;
(iii) List and summarize all agreements or instruments (with
appropriate references to specific provisions in the text of such
agreements and instruments) that support the applicant's eligibility as
a small business under the applicable designated entity provisions,
including the establishment of de facto or de jure control. Such
agreements and instruments include articles of incorporation and by-
laws, partnership agreements, shareholder agreements, voting or other
trust agreements, management agreements, franchise agreements, spectrum
leasing arrangements, spectrum resale (including wholesale)
arrangements, and any other relevant agreements (including letters of
intent), oral or written;
* * * * *
(v) List separately and in the aggregate the gross revenues,
computed in accordance with Sec. 1.2110, for each of the following:
The applicant, its affiliates, its controlling interests, and
affiliates of its controlling interests; and if a consortium of small
businesses, the members comprising the consortium; and
* * * * *
0
7. Section 1.9020 is amended by revising paragraph (d)(4) to read as
follows:
Sec. 1.9020 Spectrum manager leasing arrangements.
* * * * *
(d) * * *
(4) Designated entity/entrepreneur rules. A licensee that holds a
license pursuant to small business and/or entrepreneur provisions (see
Sec. 1.2110 and Sec. 24.709 of this chapter) and continues to be
subject to unjust enrichment requirements (see Sec. 1.2111 and Sec.
24.714 of this chapter) and/or transfer restrictions (see Sec. 24.839
of this chapter) may enter into a spectrum manager leasing arrangement
with a spectrum lessee, regardless of whether the spectrum lessee meets
the Commission's designated entity eligibility requirements (see Sec.
1.2110) or its entrepreneur eligibility requirements to hold certain C
and F block licenses in the broadband personal communications services
(see Sec. 1.2110 and Sec. 24.709 of this chapter), so long as the
spectrum manager leasing arrangement does not result in the spectrum
lessee's becoming a ``controlling interest'' or ``affiliate'' (see
Sec. 1.2110) of the licensee such that the licensee would lose its
eligibility as a designated entity or entrepreneur.
* * * * *
PART 27--MISCELLANEOUS WIRELESS COMMUNICATIONS SERVICES
0
8. The authority citation for part 27 continues to read as follows:
Authority: 47 U.S.C. 154, 301, 302a, 303, 307, 309, 332, 336,
337, 1403, 1404, 1451, and 1452, unless otherwise noted.
0
9. Section 27.1301 is amended by removing the undesignated introductory
text and revising paragraph (a) to read as follows:
Sec. 27.1301 Designated entities in the 600 MHz band.
(a) Eligibility for small business provisions.
(1) A small business is an entity that, together with its
affiliates, its controlling interests, the affiliates of its
controlling interests, and the entities with which it has an
attributable material relationship, has average gross revenues not
exceeding $55 million for the preceding three (3) years.
(2) A very small business is an entity that, together with its
affiliates, its controlling interests, the affiliates of its
controlling interests, and the entities with which it has an
attributable material relationship, has average gross revenues not
exceeding $20 million for the preceding three (3) years.
* * * * *
[FR Doc. 2014-26924 Filed 11-13-14; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6712-01-P