Centralized Capacity Markets in Regional Transmission Organizations and Independent System Operators; Notice Allowing Post-Technical Conference Comments, 65632-65634 [2013-26090]

Download as PDF 65632 Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 212 / Friday, November 1, 2013 / Notices 3, 2013 petition for waiver. Grant of this waiver does not release a petitioner from the certification requirements set forth at 10 CFR part 429. Issued in Washington, DC, on October 28, 2013. Kathleen B. Hogan Deputy Assistant Secretary for Energy Efficiency and Renewable Energy. [FR Doc. 2013–26085 Filed 10–31–13; 8:45 am] BILLING CODE 6450–01–P DEPARTMENT OF ENERGY Federal Energy Regulatory Commission [Docket No. AD13–7–000] emcdonald on DSK67QTVN1PROD with NOTICES Centralized Capacity Markets in Regional Transmission Organizations and Independent System Operators; Notice Allowing Post-Technical Conference Comments On September 25, 2013, the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (Commission) conducted a technical conference to consider how current centralized capacity market rules and structures in the regions served by ISO New England Inc. (ISO–NE), New York Independent System Operator, Inc. (NYISO), and PJM Interconnection, L.L.C. (PJM) are supporting the procurement and retention of resources necessary to meet future reliability and operational needs.1 All interested persons are invited to file post-technical conference comments on any or all of the questions listed in the attachment to this Notice. Commenters need not address every question. Commenters are also invited to rely on or cite to testimony that was previously filed in this docket and the technical conference transcript in their comments. These comments must be filed with the Commission no later than 5:00 p.m. Eastern Standard Time (EST) on Monday, December 9, 2013. For more information about this Notice, please contact: Shiv Mani (Technical Information), Office of Energy Policy and Innovation, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, 888 First Street NE., Washington, DC 20426, (202) 502– 8240, Shiv.Mani@ferc.govmailto: Kate Hoke (Legal Information), Office of the General Counsel, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, 888 First 1 While the Commission recognizes that other regions are considering similar issues, the technical conference focused solely on the centralized capacity markets in the ISO–NE, NYISO and PJM regions. Thus, post-technical conference comments should be focused on those three regions as well. VerDate Mar<15>2010 17:40 Oct 31, 2013 Jkt 232001 Street NE., Washington, DC 20426, (202) 502–8404, Katheryn.Hoke@ ferc.gov. Dated: October 25, 2013. Nathaniel J. Davis, Sr., Deputy Secretary. Post-Technical Conference Questions for Comment 1. Role of Capacity Markets and Definition of the Capacity Product Panelists discussed the definition of the capacity product and, in particular, the relationship between the capacity and energy and ancillary services markets, both today and in the future as electric system needs change. In particular, panelists addressed the importance of properly defining the capacity product, and whether additional capacity products should be defined to recognize future system operational needs. Some favored retention of the current design, procuring a single capacity product focused on meeting basic resource adequacy requirements, with any operational attributes needed to meet system requirements procured in the energy and ancillary services markets. Others favored an approach that would procure differentiated products in capacity markets, incorporating attributes that meet specific operational needs. In addition, panelists discussed how different categories of resources (traditional generation, new resources vs. existing resources, demand response, energy efficiency, distributed generation, etc.) should be valued and accounted for in centralized capacity markets. • When procuring a single capacity product, as under current market designs, are there certain fundamental performance standards that capacity resources should be required to meet in the delivery year to ensure resource adequacy? Should any such requirement change depending on the type of resource (traditional generation, new resources vs. existing resources, demand response, energy efficiency, distributed generation, etc.)? • Should existing capacity products be modified to reflect various operational characteristics needed to meet system needs? If there is a need for additional capacity products, how should those products be defined and procured in light of the current one day in ten year resource adequacy approach? • Alternatively, if it is more appropriate to rely on energy and ancillary services markets to obtain needed operational characteristics, how can market participants and regulators be confident that resources capable of PO 00000 Frm 00028 Fmt 4703 Sfmt 4703 providing such ancillary services will be available in future periods? To what extent are the existing categories of ancillary services adequate to meet current and future operational needs without a forward market? • What improvements are needed in how centralized capacity markets determine qualification as a capacity resource? Do the requirements to participate in the centralized capacity markets accommodate all resources (whether supply-side, demand-side, or imports) that are technically capable of providing the traditional forward capacity product? • As changes in technology and markets drive new system needs, are modifications needed to existing methods for determining resource adequacy requirements (i.e., the reserve margins centralized capacity markets are designed to procure)? • What is the role(s) of centralized capacity markets? Should the centralized capacity markets function as a mandatory market for procuring capacity or a residual market that entities only need to use to meet their resource adequacy obligations that they cannot otherwise meet through selfsupply? 2. Accommodating State Policies and Self-Supply by Load Serving Entities As discussed at the technical conference, States have policies to maintain resource adequacy and procure specific resources to meet environmental objectives. In addition, load serving entities are often interested in supplying their own resource adequacy requirements; some load serving entities (LSEs) have suggested that current centralized capacity market designs do not allow them to do so effectively. Incorporating States’ policies and LSE preferences in the design of capacity markets has raised challenges for the Commission in ensuring the integrity of its wholesale markets. • In what ways do the current centralized capacity market designs facilitate, or hinder, the ability of market participants to enter into arrangements to supply their own resource adequacy requirements? Should the Commission consider changes to the current capacity market designs to facilitate these arrangements? How would any potential changes impact capacity market prices paid by LSEs and the price signals provided to capacity resources? • Some panelists suggested other potential modifications to the existing centralized capacity markets to accommodate self-supply and/or state policies, including limited or resource E:\FR\FM\01NON1.SGM 01NON1 Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 212 / Friday, November 1, 2013 / Notices emcdonald on DSK67QTVN1PROD with NOTICES class-specific exemptions from buyerside mitigation rules, or offsetting reductions in the amount of capacity procured in the centralized capacity market. What are the advantages or disadvantages of such changes? Are there additional potential changes to particular design elements that should be considered to accommodate selfsupply and/or state policies? How would any potential changes accommodate the long-term price signals that several panelists argued are necessary for capacity investment? • PJM offers LSEs the alternative to opt out of its capacity auction by using the Fixed Resource Requirement (FRR) option. Should such an alternative be offered in other eastern Regional Transmission Organization (RTO)/ Independent System Operator (ISO) centralized capacity markets? Given that the FRR option was originally developed to address a narrow set of circumstances facing the PJM region and its market participants at that time, would modifications to this alternative be appropriate to meet the needs of regions and market participants today? For example, are there changes to the current FRR option that could be adopted to allow increased flexibility for entities looking to partially selfsupply their capacity requirements while preventing adverse impacts on the competitiveness of the market? 3. Market Design Elements Throughout the technical conference, comparisons of the RTO/ISO capacity markets and market design elements were made, including whether there is a need for consistency in the approach to capacity markets across the eastern RTOs/ISOs and the interaction of the capacity market with other RTO/ISO markets. Panelists suggested that consistent approaches with respect to some design elements could improve the ability of market participants to participate in multiple markets. • Slope of demand curve. A number of panelists commented that a downward-sloping demand curve is preferable to a vertical demand curve. What are the advantages and disadvantages of a sloped demand curve versus a vertical demand curve? What are the key design criteria appropriate to consider in establishing the slope of the demand curve in each of the eastern RTO/ISO centralized capacity markets? • Derivation of Resource Adequacy Requirements. Whether using a sloped or vertical demand curve, RTOs/ISOs must attempt to accurately assess future capacity needs in order to ensure resource adequacy in the delivery year. Are there improvements to the VerDate Mar<15>2010 17:40 Oct 31, 2013 Jkt 232001 derivation of an RTO/ISO’s resource adequacy requirement that would improve the functioning of its capacity market? How do differences in the derivation of resource adequacy requirements across the RTOs/ISOs impact the markets? For RTOs/ISOs with three-year forward markets, should the RTO/ISO procure 100 percent of its resource adequacy requirement three years in advance of the delivery year, or is there a portion of the resource adequacy requirement that can be reliably procured closer to the delivery year? What are the advantages and disadvantages of procuring a portion of the resource adequacy requirement closer to the delivery year? • Derivation of Net Cost of New Entry (CONE). Panelists did not focus extensively on the derivation of Net CONE, although it was discussed in the staff white paper. Are there improvements to the derivation of Net CONE that would improve the functioning of capacity markets? How do differences in the derivation of Net CONE across the RTOs/ISOs impact the markets? • Length of forward period. Panelists debated the merits of a longer or shorter forward period in centralized capacity markets. Some argued that a longer forward period can aid in managing retirements; others argued that a shorter forward period facilitates bilateral contracting. What are the advantages, disadvantages and related considerations that may support longer or shorter forward periods? Should the length of the forward period vary for different categories of resources (traditional generation, new resources vs. existing resources, demand response, energy efficiency, distributed generation, etc.)? • Length of commitment period. Commitment periods also vary by RTO/ ISO and by resource-type. Is there an ideal length of the commitment period? Should the length of commitment period vary for different categories of resources (traditional generation, new resources vs. existing resources, demand response, energy efficiency, distributed generation, etc.)? Does the length of the commitment period impact the ability and willingness of buyers and sellers to enter into bilateral contracts? How do differences in commitment periods across the RTOs/ISOs impact the markets? • Zones. Some panelists at the technical conference asserted that capacity market zones are not sufficiently granular and do not change often enough to reflect important market and system changes. Are there advantages or disadvantages associated PO 00000 Frm 00029 Fmt 4703 Sfmt 4703 65633 with increasing the granularity of capacity zones? If so, what are they? What are the challenges, advantages or disadvantages of a dynamic approach to establishing capacity zones? • Coordination of transmission planning and capacity market. Price signals in the capacity markets also provide information to transmission planners to the extent that transmission may substitute for capacity resources. How can investment in capacity and transmission planning be better coordinated? Should the capacity market planning process and transmission planning process use common assumptions and common planning horizons? • Retirement notice. What role do retirement and mothballing decisions and notification play in the operation of the eastern RTO/ISO centralized capacity markets? Is there an ideal approach to retirement or mothballing notification? What is the impact of different retirement or mothballing notice procedures across the eastern RTOs/ISOs on the market, resource adequacy and reliability? 4. Regulatory Certainty Several panelists stated the importance of regulatory certainty in achieving capacity market stability. Regulatory certainty reduces risk and thereby lowers barriers to entry in capacity markets. Conversely, some panelists identified significant market design issues that, if resolved, could improve capacity market efficacy. While recognizing that regional differences may be necessary, some panelists suggested that a minimum level of best practices across the three eastern RTO/ ISO centralized capacity markets also would lead to greater regulatory certainty and provide inter-regional benefits. • How should the Commission strike a reasonable balance in adopting market rule changes when necessary without creating undue regulatory uncertainty? • What are the advantages and disadvantages of an RTO/ISO regularly revisiting certain market design elements, such as NYISO’s triennial reset of its capacity demand curve? 5. Next Steps Conference panelists indicated that further direction from the Commission could help to inform the development of appropriate eastern RTO/ISO centralized capacity market design elements in the future. • What Commission action would be an appropriate next step with respect to those markets? E:\FR\FM\01NON1.SGM 01NON1 65634 Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 212 / Friday, November 1, 2013 / Notices • Are there outstanding issues or questions raised by, but not fully discussed at, the conference that should be considered in this proceeding? • Are there other issues that, if addressed, would help the centralized capacity markets ensure resource adequacy in a just and reasonable and not unduly discriminatory manner (e.g., enhancements to the energy and ancillary services markets) that should be considered by the Commission in another forum? [FR Doc. 2013–26090 Filed 10–31–13; 8:45 am] BILLING CODE 6717–01–P DEPARTMENT OF ENERGY Federal Energy Regulatory Commission emcdonald on DSK67QTVN1PROD with NOTICES Combined Notice of Filings #1 Take notice that the Commission received the following electric rate filings: Docket Numbers: ER11–1858–002, ER11–1859–001. Applicants: NorthWestern Corporation. Description: NorthWestern Energy and Montana Generation, LLC submits the Triennial Market Power Update Analysis for Markets in the Northwest Region pursuant to Order No. 697. Filed Date: 10/18/13. Accession Number: 20131022–0006. Comments Due: 5 p.m. ET 12/17/13. Docket Numbers: ER11–4436–002; ER10–2473–003; ER10–2502–003; ER10–2472–003; ER11–2724–003. Applicants: Black Hills Power, Inc., Cheyenne Light Fuel & Power Company, Black Hills/Colorado Electric Utility Co, LP, Black Hills Colorado IPP, LLC, Black Hills Wyoming, LLC. Description: Amendment to June 28, 2013 Updated Market Power Analysis of the Black Hills Corporation Public Utilities for the Northwest Region. Filed Date: 10/23/13. Accession Number: 20131023–5055. Comments Due: 5 p.m. ET 11/13/13. Docket Numbers: ER13–1556–001. Applicants: Entergy Services, Inc. Description: Entergy Services, Inc., Amended Service Agreements to be effective 12/19/2013. Filed Date: 10/22/13. Accession Number: 20131022–5117. Comments Due: 5 p.m. ET 11/12/13. Docket Numbers: ER14–156–000. Applicants: Southern California Edison Company. Description: Amended SGIAs and Distrib Serv Agmts EDPR Agincourt LLC and EDPR Marathon LLC to be effective 10/23/2013. VerDate Mar<15>2010 17:40 Oct 31, 2013 Jkt 232001 Filed Date: 10/22/13. Accession Number: 20131022–5089. Comments Due: 5 p.m. ET 11/12/13. Docket Numbers: ER14–158–000. Applicants: Merchant’s Plaza Energy, LLC. Description: Cancellation of MBR Tariff to be effective 10/22/2013. Filed Date: 10/22/13. Accession Number: 20131022–5102. Comments Due: 5 p.m. ET 11/12/13. Docket Numbers: ER14–159–000. Applicants: Freedom Logistics, LLC. Description: Notice of Cancellation of MBR Tariff to be effective 10/22/2013. Filed Date: 10/22/13. Accession Number: 20131022–5106. Comments Due: 5 p.m. ET 11/12/13. Docket Numbers: ER14–160–000. Applicants: Entergy Gulf States Louisiana, L.L.C., Entergy Texas, Inc., Entergy Louisiana, LLC. Description: A&R Toledo Bend PSA 10–22–2013 to be effective 12/19/2013. Filed Date: 10/22/13. Accession Number: 20131022–5111. Comments Due: 5 p.m. ET 11/12/13. Docket Numbers: ER14–161–000. Applicants: American Electric Power Service Corporation, AEP Indiana Michigan Transmission Company, Indiana Michigan Power Company, Wabash Valley Power Association, Inc., PJM Interconnection, L.L.C. Description: AEP submits 10th Revised ILDSA among AEPSC & Wabash Valley Power-PJM SA No. 1262 to be effective 9/17/2010. Filed Date: 10/22/13. Accession Number: 20131022–5115. Comments Due: 5 p.m. ET 11/12/13. Docket Numbers: ER14–162–000. Applicants: Westwood Generation, LLC. Description: Compliance Update to be effective 10/23/2013. Filed Date: 10/23/13. Accession Number: 20131023–5015. Comments Due: 5 p.m. ET 11/13/13. Docket Numbers: ER14–163–000. Applicants: Southwest Power Pool, Inc. Description: 1839R2 City of Osage NITSA NOA Ministerial Filing to be effective 8/1/2013. Filed Date: 10/23/13. Accession Number: 20131023–5038. Comments Due: 5 p.m. ET 11/13/13. Docket Numbers: ER14–164–000. Applicants: Southern California Edison Company. Description: Southern California Edison Company submits tariff filing per 35.13(a)(2)(iii: Amended LGIA with Mojave Solar, LLC to be effective 10/24/ 2013. Filed Date: 10/23/13. PO 00000 Frm 00030 Fmt 4703 Sfmt 4703 Accession Number: 20131023–5058. Comments Due: 5 p.m. ET 11/13/13. Docket Numbers: ER14–165–000. Applicants: Southern California Edison Company. Description: Southern California Edison Company submits tariff filing per 35.13(a)(2)(iii: Revised Added Facilities Rate for Sycamore, Kern River, and KM Acquisitions to be effective 5/ 15/2013. Filed Date: 10/23/13. Accession Number: 20131023–5060. Comments Due: 5 p.m. ET 11/13/13. Docket Numbers: ER14–166–000. Applicants: Rigby Energy Resources, LP. Description: Rigby Energy Resources, LP submits tariff filing per 35.12: Initial Filing to be effective 12/23/2013. Filed Date: 10/23/13. Accession Number: 20131023–5073. Comments Due: 5 p.m. ET 11/13/13. The filings are accessible in the Commission’s eLibrary system by clicking on the links or querying the docket number. Any person desiring to intervene or protest in any of the above proceedings must file in accordance with Rules 211 and 214 of the Commission’s Regulations (18 CFR 385.211 and 385.214) on or before 5:00 p.m. Eastern time on the specified comment date. Protests may be considered, but intervention is necessary to become a party to the proceeding. eFiling is encouraged. More detailed information relating to filing requirements, interventions, protests, service, and qualifying facilities filings can be found at: https://www.ferc.gov/ docs-filing/efiling/filing-req.pdf. For other information, call (866) 208–3676 (toll free). For TTY, call (202) 502–8659. Dated: October 23, 2013. Nathaniel J. Davis, Sr., Deputy Secretary. [FR Doc. 2013–26091 Filed 10–31–13; 8:45 am] BILLING CODE 6717–01–P DEPARTMENT OF ENERGY Federal Energy Regulatory Commission Combined Notice of Filings #2 Take notice that the Commission received the following electric corporate filings: Docket Numbers: EC14–13–000. Applicants: Portland General Electric Company, BA Leasing BSC, LLC, FaleSafe Incorporated. Description: Application of Portland General Electric Company, BA Leasing E:\FR\FM\01NON1.SGM 01NON1

Agencies

[Federal Register Volume 78, Number 212 (Friday, November 1, 2013)]
[Notices]
[Pages 65632-65634]
From the Federal Register Online via the Government Printing Office [www.gpo.gov]
[FR Doc No: 2013-26090]


-----------------------------------------------------------------------

DEPARTMENT OF ENERGY

Federal Energy Regulatory Commission

[Docket No. AD13-7-000]


Centralized Capacity Markets in Regional Transmission 
Organizations and Independent System Operators; Notice Allowing Post-
Technical Conference Comments

    On September 25, 2013, the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission 
(Commission) conducted a technical conference to consider how current 
centralized capacity market rules and structures in the regions served 
by ISO New England Inc. (ISO-NE), New York Independent System Operator, 
Inc. (NYISO), and PJM Interconnection, L.L.C. (PJM) are supporting the 
procurement and retention of resources necessary to meet future 
reliability and operational needs.\1\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \1\ While the Commission recognizes that other regions are 
considering similar issues, the technical conference focused solely 
on the centralized capacity markets in the ISO-NE, NYISO and PJM 
regions. Thus, post-technical conference comments should be focused 
on those three regions as well.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    All interested persons are invited to file post-technical 
conference comments on any or all of the questions listed in the 
attachment to this Notice. Commenters need not address every question. 
Commenters are also invited to rely on or cite to testimony that was 
previously filed in this docket and the technical conference transcript 
in their comments. These comments must be filed with the Commission no 
later than 5:00 p.m. Eastern Standard Time (EST) on Monday, December 9, 
2013.
    For more information about this Notice, please contact:

Shiv Mani (Technical Information), Office of Energy Policy and 
Innovation, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, 888 First Street NE., 
Washington, DC 20426, (202) 502-8240, Shiv.Mani@ferc.govmailto:
Kate Hoke (Legal Information), Office of the General Counsel, Federal 
Energy Regulatory Commission, 888 First Street NE., Washington, DC 
20426, (202) 502-8404, Katheryn.Hoke@ferc.gov.

    Dated: October 25, 2013.
Nathaniel J. Davis, Sr.,
Deputy Secretary.

Post-Technical Conference Questions for Comment

1. Role of Capacity Markets and Definition of the Capacity Product

    Panelists discussed the definition of the capacity product and, in 
particular, the relationship between the capacity and energy and 
ancillary services markets, both today and in the future as electric 
system needs change. In particular, panelists addressed the importance 
of properly defining the capacity product, and whether additional 
capacity products should be defined to recognize future system 
operational needs. Some favored retention of the current design, 
procuring a single capacity product focused on meeting basic resource 
adequacy requirements, with any operational attributes needed to meet 
system requirements procured in the energy and ancillary services 
markets. Others favored an approach that would procure differentiated 
products in capacity markets, incorporating attributes that meet 
specific operational needs. In addition, panelists discussed how 
different categories of resources (traditional generation, new 
resources vs. existing resources, demand response, energy efficiency, 
distributed generation, etc.) should be valued and accounted for in 
centralized capacity markets.
     When procuring a single capacity product, as under current 
market designs, are there certain fundamental performance standards 
that capacity resources should be required to meet in the delivery year 
to ensure resource adequacy? Should any such requirement change 
depending on the type of resource (traditional generation, new 
resources vs. existing resources, demand response, energy efficiency, 
distributed generation, etc.)?
     Should existing capacity products be modified to reflect 
various operational characteristics needed to meet system needs? If 
there is a need for additional capacity products, how should those 
products be defined and procured in light of the current one day in ten 
year resource adequacy approach?
     Alternatively, if it is more appropriate to rely on energy 
and ancillary services markets to obtain needed operational 
characteristics, how can market participants and regulators be 
confident that resources capable of providing such ancillary services 
will be available in future periods? To what extent are the existing 
categories of ancillary services adequate to meet current and future 
operational needs without a forward market?
     What improvements are needed in how centralized capacity 
markets determine qualification as a capacity resource? Do the 
requirements to participate in the centralized capacity markets 
accommodate all resources (whether supply-side, demand-side, or 
imports) that are technically capable of providing the traditional 
forward capacity product?
     As changes in technology and markets drive new system 
needs, are modifications needed to existing methods for determining 
resource adequacy requirements (i.e., the reserve margins centralized 
capacity markets are designed to procure)?
     What is the role(s) of centralized capacity markets? 
Should the centralized capacity markets function as a mandatory market 
for procuring capacity or a residual market that entities only need to 
use to meet their resource adequacy obligations that they cannot 
otherwise meet through self-supply?

2. Accommodating State Policies and Self-Supply by Load Serving 
Entities

    As discussed at the technical conference, States have policies to 
maintain resource adequacy and procure specific resources to meet 
environmental objectives. In addition, load serving entities are often 
interested in supplying their own resource adequacy requirements; some 
load serving entities (LSEs) have suggested that current centralized 
capacity market designs do not allow them to do so effectively. 
Incorporating States' policies and LSE preferences in the design of 
capacity markets has raised challenges for the Commission in ensuring 
the integrity of its wholesale markets.
     In what ways do the current centralized capacity market 
designs facilitate, or hinder, the ability of market participants to 
enter into arrangements to supply their own resource adequacy 
requirements? Should the Commission consider changes to the current 
capacity market designs to facilitate these arrangements? How would any 
potential changes impact capacity market prices paid by LSEs and the 
price signals provided to capacity resources?
     Some panelists suggested other potential modifications to 
the existing centralized capacity markets to accommodate self-supply 
and/or state policies, including limited or resource

[[Page 65633]]

class-specific exemptions from buyer-side mitigation rules, or 
offsetting reductions in the amount of capacity procured in the 
centralized capacity market. What are the advantages or disadvantages 
of such changes? Are there additional potential changes to particular 
design elements that should be considered to accommodate self-supply 
and/or state policies? How would any potential changes accommodate the 
long-term price signals that several panelists argued are necessary for 
capacity investment?
     PJM offers LSEs the alternative to opt out of its capacity 
auction by using the Fixed Resource Requirement (FRR) option. Should 
such an alternative be offered in other eastern Regional Transmission 
Organization (RTO)/Independent System Operator (ISO) centralized 
capacity markets? Given that the FRR option was originally developed to 
address a narrow set of circumstances facing the PJM region and its 
market participants at that time, would modifications to this 
alternative be appropriate to meet the needs of regions and market 
participants today? For example, are there changes to the current FRR 
option that could be adopted to allow increased flexibility for 
entities looking to partially self-supply their capacity requirements 
while preventing adverse impacts on the competitiveness of the market?

3. Market Design Elements

    Throughout the technical conference, comparisons of the RTO/ISO 
capacity markets and market design elements were made, including 
whether there is a need for consistency in the approach to capacity 
markets across the eastern RTOs/ISOs and the interaction of the 
capacity market with other RTO/ISO markets. Panelists suggested that 
consistent approaches with respect to some design elements could 
improve the ability of market participants to participate in multiple 
markets.
     Slope of demand curve. A number of panelists commented 
that a downward-sloping demand curve is preferable to a vertical demand 
curve. What are the advantages and disadvantages of a sloped demand 
curve versus a vertical demand curve? What are the key design criteria 
appropriate to consider in establishing the slope of the demand curve 
in each of the eastern RTO/ISO centralized capacity markets?
     Derivation of Resource Adequacy Requirements. Whether 
using a sloped or vertical demand curve, RTOs/ISOs must attempt to 
accurately assess future capacity needs in order to ensure resource 
adequacy in the delivery year. Are there improvements to the derivation 
of an RTO/ISO's resource adequacy requirement that would improve the 
functioning of its capacity market? How do differences in the 
derivation of resource adequacy requirements across the RTOs/ISOs 
impact the markets? For RTOs/ISOs with three-year forward markets, 
should the RTO/ISO procure 100 percent of its resource adequacy 
requirement three years in advance of the delivery year, or is there a 
portion of the resource adequacy requirement that can be reliably 
procured closer to the delivery year? What are the advantages and 
disadvantages of procuring a portion of the resource adequacy 
requirement closer to the delivery year?
     Derivation of Net Cost of New Entry (CONE). Panelists did 
not focus extensively on the derivation of Net CONE, although it was 
discussed in the staff white paper. Are there improvements to the 
derivation of Net CONE that would improve the functioning of capacity 
markets? How do differences in the derivation of Net CONE across the 
RTOs/ISOs impact the markets?
     Length of forward period. Panelists debated the merits of 
a longer or shorter forward period in centralized capacity markets. 
Some argued that a longer forward period can aid in managing 
retirements; others argued that a shorter forward period facilitates 
bilateral contracting. What are the advantages, disadvantages and 
related considerations that may support longer or shorter forward 
periods? Should the length of the forward period vary for different 
categories of resources (traditional generation, new resources vs. 
existing resources, demand response, energy efficiency, distributed 
generation, etc.)?
     Length of commitment period. Commitment periods also vary 
by RTO/ISO and by resource-type. Is there an ideal length of the 
commitment period? Should the length of commitment period vary for 
different categories of resources (traditional generation, new 
resources vs. existing resources, demand response, energy efficiency, 
distributed generation, etc.)? Does the length of the commitment period 
impact the ability and willingness of buyers and sellers to enter into 
bilateral contracts? How do differences in commitment periods across 
the RTOs/ISOs impact the markets?
     Zones. Some panelists at the technical conference asserted 
that capacity market zones are not sufficiently granular and do not 
change often enough to reflect important market and system changes. Are 
there advantages or disadvantages associated with increasing the 
granularity of capacity zones? If so, what are they? What are the 
challenges, advantages or disadvantages of a dynamic approach to 
establishing capacity zones?
     Coordination of transmission planning and capacity market. 
Price signals in the capacity markets also provide information to 
transmission planners to the extent that transmission may substitute 
for capacity resources. How can investment in capacity and transmission 
planning be better coordinated? Should the capacity market planning 
process and transmission planning process use common assumptions and 
common planning horizons?
     Retirement notice. What role do retirement and mothballing 
decisions and notification play in the operation of the eastern RTO/ISO 
centralized capacity markets? Is there an ideal approach to retirement 
or mothballing notification? What is the impact of different retirement 
or mothballing notice procedures across the eastern RTOs/ISOs on the 
market, resource adequacy and reliability?

4. Regulatory Certainty

    Several panelists stated the importance of regulatory certainty in 
achieving capacity market stability. Regulatory certainty reduces risk 
and thereby lowers barriers to entry in capacity markets. Conversely, 
some panelists identified significant market design issues that, if 
resolved, could improve capacity market efficacy. While recognizing 
that regional differences may be necessary, some panelists suggested 
that a minimum level of best practices across the three eastern RTO/ISO 
centralized capacity markets also would lead to greater regulatory 
certainty and provide inter-regional benefits.
     How should the Commission strike a reasonable balance in 
adopting market rule changes when necessary without creating undue 
regulatory uncertainty?
     What are the advantages and disadvantages of an RTO/ISO 
regularly revisiting certain market design elements, such as NYISO's 
triennial reset of its capacity demand curve?

5. Next Steps

    Conference panelists indicated that further direction from the 
Commission could help to inform the development of appropriate eastern 
RTO/ISO centralized capacity market design elements in the future.
     What Commission action would be an appropriate next step 
with respect to those markets?

[[Page 65634]]

     Are there outstanding issues or questions raised by, but 
not fully discussed at, the conference that should be considered in 
this proceeding?
     Are there other issues that, if addressed, would help the 
centralized capacity markets ensure resource adequacy in a just and 
reasonable and not unduly discriminatory manner (e.g., enhancements to 
the energy and ancillary services markets) that should be considered by 
the Commission in another forum?

[FR Doc. 2013-26090 Filed 10-31-13; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6717-01-P
This site is protected by reCAPTCHA and the Google Privacy Policy and Terms of Service apply.