Clearing Exemption for Certain Swaps Entered Into by Cooperatives, 52285-52308 [2013-19945]
Download as PDF
Vol. 78
Thursday,
No. 163
August 22, 2013
Part III
Commodity Futures Trading Commission
tkelley on DSK3SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
17 CFR Parts 4 and 50
Clearing Exemption for Certain Swaps Entered Into by Cooperatives;
Harmonization of Compliance Obligations for Registered Investment
Companies Required To Register as Commodity Pool Operators; Final
Rules
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:26 Aug 21, 2013
Jkt 229001
PO 00000
Frm 00001
Fmt 4717
Sfmt 4717
E:\FR\FM\22AUR2.SGM
22AUR2
52286
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 163 / Thursday, August 22, 2013 / Rules and Regulations
COMMODITY FUTURES TRADING
COMMISSION
17 CFR Part 50
RIN 3038–AD47
Clearing Exemption for Certain Swaps
Entered Into by Cooperatives
Commodity Futures Trading
Commission.
ACTION: Final rule.
AGENCY:
The Commodity Futures
Trading Commission (‘‘CFTC’’ or
‘‘Commission’’) is adopting final
regulations pursuant to its authority
under section 4(c) of the Commodity
Exchange Act (‘‘CEA’’) allowing
cooperatives meeting certain conditions
to elect not to submit for clearing certain
swaps that such cooperatives would
otherwise be required to submit for
clearing in accordance with section
2(h)(1) of the CEA.
DATES: Effective September 23, 2013.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
Brian O’Keefe, Deputy Director, 202–
418–5658, bokeefe@cftc.gov, Division of
Clearing and Risk, or Erik F. Remmler,
Deputy Director, 202–418–7630,
eremmler@cftc.gov, Division of Swap
Dealer and Intermediary Oversight,
Commodity Futures Trading
Commission, Three Lafayette Centre,
1155 21st Street NW., Washington, DC
20581.
SUMMARY:
tkelley on DSK3SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
I. Background
The CEA, as amended by Title VII of
the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and
Consumer Protection Act (the ‘‘DoddFrank Act’’),1 establishes a
comprehensive new regulatory
framework for swaps. The CEA requires
a swap: (1) To be submitted for clearing
through a derivatives clearing
organization (‘‘DCO’’) if the Commission
has determined that the swap is
required to be cleared, unless an
exception or exemption to the clearing
requirement applies; (2) to be reported
to a swap data repository (‘‘SDR’’) or the
Commission; and (3) if such swap is
subject to a clearing requirement, to be
executed on a designated contract
market (‘‘DCM’’) or swap execution
facility (‘‘SEF’’), unless no DCM or SEF
has made the swap available to trade.
Section 2(h)(1)(A) of the CEA
establishes a clearing requirement for
swaps, providing that ‘‘[i]t shall be
unlawful for any person to engage in a
swap unless that person submits such
swap for clearing to a [DCO] that is
1 See Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and
Consumer Protection Act, Public Law 111–203, 124
Stat. 1376 (2010).
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:26 Aug 21, 2013
Jkt 229001
registered under [the CEA] or a [DCO]
that is exempt from registration under
[the CEA] if the swap is required to be
cleared.’’ 2 However, section 2(h)(7)(A)
of the CEA provides that the clearing
requirement of section 2(h)(1)(A) shall
not apply to a swap if one of the
counterparties to the swap: ‘‘(i) is not a
financial entity; (ii) is using swaps to
hedge or mitigate commercial risk; and
(iii) notifies the Commission, in a
manner set forth by the Commission,
how it generally meets its financial
obligations associated with entering into
non-cleared swaps’’ (referred to
hereinafter as the ‘‘end-user
exception’’).3 The Commission has
adopted § 39.6 (now recodified as
§ 50.50 4) to implement certain
provisions of section 2(h)(7).
Accordingly, any swap that is required
to be cleared by the Commission
pursuant to section 2(h)(2) of the CEA
must be submitted to a DCO for clearing
by the counterparties unless the
conditions of § 50.50 are satisfied or
another exemption adopted by the
Commission applies.
Congress adopted the end-user
exception in section 2(h)(7) of the CEA
to permit certain non-financial entities
to continue using non-cleared swaps to
hedge or mitigate risks associated with
their underlying businesses, such as
manufacturing, energy exploration,
farming, transportation, or other
commercial activities. Additionally, in
section 2(h)(7)(C)(ii) of the CEA, the
Commission was directed to ‘‘consider
whether to exempt [from the definition
of ‘financial entity’] small banks,
savings associations, farm credit system
institutions, and credit unions,
including:
(I) Depository institutions with total
assets of $10,000,000,000 or less;
(II) farm credit system institutions
with total assets of $10,000,000,000 or
less; or
(III) credit unions with total assets of
$10,000,000,000 or less.’’
In § 50.50(d), the Commission
identifies which financial entities are
small financial institutions and
establishes an exemption from the
definition of ‘‘financial entity’’ for these
small financial institutions pursuant to
section 2(h)(7)(C)(ii) (the ‘‘small
financial institution exemption’’). The
2 See section 2(h)(1)(A) of the CEA, 7 U.S.C.
2(h)(1)(A).
3 See section 2(h)(7)(A) of the CEA, 7 U.S.C.
2(h)(7)(A).
4 77 FR 74284 (Dec. 13, 2012). The Commission
re-codified the end-user exception regulations as
§ 50.50 so that market participants are able to locate
all rules related to the clearing requirement in one
part of the Code of Federal Regulations. Because of
this re-codification, all citations thereto in this final
release will be to the sections as renumbered.
PO 00000
Frm 00002
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
small financial institution exemption
largely adopts the language of section
2(h)(7)(C)(ii) in providing for an
exemption from the definition of
‘‘financial entity’’ for the types of
section 2(h)(7)(C)(ii) institutions having
total assets of $10 billion or less.
On December 23, 2010, the
Commission published for public
comment a notice of proposed
rulemaking (‘‘end-user exception
NPRM’’) to implement the end-user
exception.5 Several parties that
commented on the end-user exception
NPRM recommended that the
Commission extend relief from clearing
to cooperatives.6 These commenters
primarily reasoned 7 that the member
ownership nature of cooperatives and
the fact that cooperatives act in the
interests of members that are nonfinancial entities or cooperatives whose
members are non-financial entities,
justified allowing the cooperatives to
also elect the end-user exception. In
effect, they proposed that because a
cooperative acts in the interests of its
members when facing the larger
financial markets, the end-user
exception that would be available to a
cooperative’s members should also be
available to the cooperative.
Accordingly, commenters asserted, if
the members themselves could elect the
end-user exception, then the
Commission should permit the
cooperatives to do so as well.8
5 See
75 FR 80747 (Dec. 23, 2010).
e.g., comments received on the end-user
exception NPRM from: Agricultural Leaders of
Michigan (ALM), The Farm Credit Council (FCC),
Allegheny Electric Cooperative, Inc. (AEC), Garkane
Energy Cooperative, Inc. (GEC), National Council of
Farmer Cooperatives, Dairy Farmers of America,
and National Rural Utilities Cooperative Finance
Corporation (CFC). Comments received on the enduser exception NPRM can be found on the
Commission’s Web site at https://comments.cftc.gov/
PublicComments/CommentList.aspx?id=937.
7 Other reasons given for providing an exemption
from clearing to cooperatives, including risk
considerations, are discussed below.
8 In addition to the comments received on the
end-user exception NPRM, the Commission notes
that several Senators and members of the House of
Representatives have expressed similar support in
committee hearings for ensuring that the
implementation of the Dodd-Frank Act does not
change the way financial cooperatives operate in
relation to their members. See, e.g., Oversight
Hearing: Implementation of Title VII of the Wall St.
Reform and Consumer Prot. Act Before the S.
Comm. on Agric., 112th Cong. 18 (2011) (statement
of Sen. Debbie Stabenow, Chairwoman, S. Comm.
on Agric.) (‘‘I just want to make sure that . . .
you’re saying or that you’re going to guarantee that
the relationship between farmers and co-ops will be
preserved and that farmers will continue to have
affordable access to risk management tools.’’); One
Year Later—The Wall St. Reform and Consumer
Prot. Act: Hearing Before the S. Comm. on Agric.,
112th Cong. 14 (statement of Sen. Amy Klobuchar,
Member, S. Comm. on Agric.) (‘‘I hope there is a
way to uniquely define farmer co-ops so they can
continue to do the kinds of things that they do.’’);
6 See,
E:\FR\FM\22AUR2.SGM
22AUR2
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 163 / Thursday, August 22, 2013 / Rules and Regulations
tkelley on DSK3SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
However, section 2(h)(7) of the CEA
does not differentiate cooperatives from
other types of entities and therefore,
cooperatives that are ‘‘financial
entities,’’ as defined in section 2(h)(7)(i)
of the CEA, are unable to elect the enduser exception unless they qualify for
the small financial institution
exemption. Some commenters
recommended including cooperatives
that are ‘‘financial entities’’ with total
assets in excess of $10 billion in the
small financial institution exemption.9
However, as explained in greater detail
in the final release for § 50.50, section
2(h)(7)(C)(ii) of the CEA focused on
asset size and not on the structure of the
financial entity. Accordingly, only
cooperatives that are financial entities
with total assets of $10 billion or less
can qualify as small financial
institutions under the small financial
institution exemption.
Notwithstanding the foregoing, the
Commission recognized that the
member-owner structure of cooperatives
and the merits of effectively allowing
cooperatives to also use the end-user
exception when acting in the interests of
their members, warranted consideration.
Accordingly, the Commission is using
the authority provided in section 4(c) of
the CEA to finalize § 50.51 (proposed as
§ 39.6(f) 10), to permit cooperatives that
meet certain qualifications to elect not
to clear certain swaps that are otherwise
required to be cleared pursuant to
section 2(h)(1)(A) of the CEA
(hereinafter referred to as the
‘‘cooperative exemption’’). Under
section 4(c) of the CEA, the Commission
can subject such exemptive relief to
appropriate terms and conditions.11
Derivatives Reform: the View from Main St.:
Hearing Before the H. Comm. on Agric., 112th Cong.
12 (2011) (statement of Rep. Timothy Johnson,
Member, H. Comm. on Agric.) (‘‘I’m also concerned,
real concerned, representing an area, as a lot of us
do, where rural electric cooperatives, agricultural
cooperatives, and all that are an essential part of our
being, critical, positive entities that really do a
whole lot for the infrastructure of this country. . . .
And I’m very concerned that we’re treating, in
many ways, and you are, those cooperatives in a
way almost identical to Goldman Sachs, and I think
that’s—frankly, I think that fall[s] of its own
weight.’’); The Commodity Futures Trading
Comm’n 2012 Agenda: Hearing Before the H.
Comm. on Agric., 112th Cong. 13 (2012) (statement
of Rep. Rick Crawford, Member, H. Comm. on
Agric.) (‘‘[Agricultural cooperatives provide] swaps
to their members and then enter into [another swap
to offset that risk]. This is critical to their ability to
continue [to provide] hedging tools to member[s] of
their coops. . . . ’’).
9 See, e.g., comments received on the end-user
exception NPRM from: FCC, CFC, AEC, ALM, and
GEC.
10 For ease of reference, the Commission is recodifying proposed § 39.6(f) as § 50.51 so that
market participants are able to locate all rules
related to the clearing requirement in one part of
the Code of Federal Regulations.
11 7 U.S.C. 6(c)(1).
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:26 Aug 21, 2013
Jkt 229001
On July 17, 2012, the Commission
published for public comment a notice
of proposed rulemaking (‘‘NPRM’’)
proposing the cooperative exemption as
§ 39.6(f) (now § 50.51).12 The
Commission explained that cooperatives
have a unique legal structure that
differentiates them from other legal
business structures in terms of how they
are operated and who benefits from
their activities. In a cooperative, the
members of the cooperative are the
principal customers of the cooperative
and are also the owners of the
cooperative. Accordingly, the
cooperatives exist to serve their
member-owners and do not act for their
own profit.13 The member-owners of the
cooperative collectively have full
control over the governance of the
cooperative. In a real sense, a
cooperative is not separable from its
member-owners. The cooperative exists
to act in the mutual interests of its
member-owners in the marketplace.
As described in greater detail below
in section II, some cooperatives provide
financial services to their members
including lending and providing swaps,
and the cooperatives sometimes hedge
or mitigate risks associated with those
lending activities with other financial
entities such as swap dealers (‘‘SDs’’).
The memberships of some of these
cooperatives consist of entities that can
each elect the end-user exception when
entering into a swap. However, the enduser exception is unavailable to some of
those cooperatives because they fall
within the definition of ‘‘financial
entity’’ and have assets in excess of $10
billion. Accordingly, if the cooperative
members continue to enter into loans
and swaps with their cooperative, they
would not receive the full benefits of the
end-user exception because the
cooperative would have to clear its
swaps even though it is entering into the
swaps to offset the risks associated with
financial activities with its members or
to hedge risks associated with wholesale
borrowing activities, the proceeds of
which are used to fund member loans.
In effect, absent an exception from the
clearing requirement for a cooperative
that is providing certain swap services
to its members, the cooperative
structure would be unable—solely
12 77
FR 41940 (July 17, 2012).
example, the CFC was formed as a
nonprofit corporation under the District of
Columbia Cooperative Association Act of 1940 to
arrange financing for its members and their patrons
and for the ‘‘primary and mutual benefit of the
patrons of the Association and their patrons, as
ultimate consumers.’’ CFC Articles of Incorporation
and Bylaws, Art. I, (last amended Mar. 1, 2005),
available at https://www.nrucfc.coop/content/dam/
cfc_assets/public_tier/publicDocs/governance/
CFCbylaws_3_11.pdf.
52287
because the cooperative is large and has
substantial assets—to achieve the
intended benefits for its members who
can elect the end-user exception. In
light of the foregoing, the Commission is
exercising its authority under section
4(c) of the CEA to establish the
cooperative exemption.
The Commission received
approximately 25 comment letters and
Commission staff participated in
approximately two ex parte meetings
concerning the cooperative exemption
NPRM.14 The Commission considered
these comments in formulating the final
regulations, as discussed below.
II. Financial Entity Cooperatives
In the NPRM, the Commission
described the structure of cooperatives
that provide financial services to their
members to provide context for the
underlying rationale for the proposed
cooperative exemption. The description
provided in the NPRM is summarized
below to facilitate an understanding of
the comments received and the
Commission’s responses thereto.
Cooperatives that are ‘‘financial
entities,’’ as defined in section
2(h)(7)(C)(i) of the CEA, generally serve
as collective asset and liability managers
for their members. In this role, the
cooperatives, in effect, face the financial
markets as intermediaries for their
members. These cooperatives sometimes
enter into swaps with members and
with non-member counterparties,
typically SDs or other financial entities,
to hedge the risks associated with the
swaps or loans they execute with their
members, or to hedge risks associated
with their wholesale borrowing
activities, the proceeds of which are
used to fund member loans. If these
financial entity cooperatives have total
assets in excess of $10 billion, then the
cooperatives do not qualify for the small
financial institution exemption and thus
cannot elect the end-user exception.
Some cooperatives with more than
$10 billion in total assets have members
that are non-financial entities, small
financial institutions, or other
cooperatives whose members consist of
such entities.15 For example, there are
four Farm Credit System (‘‘FCS’’) banks
chartered under Federal law, each of
which has total assets in excess of $10
billion.16 The FCS banks are
13 For
PO 00000
Frm 00003
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
14 All comments received in response to the
cooperative exemption NPRM can be viewed on the
Commission’s Web site at https://comments.cftc.gov/
PublicComments/CommentList.aspx?id=1237.
15 See, e.g., comments received on the end-user
exception NPRM from FCC, CFC, AEC, ALM, and
GEC.
16 See FCA, 2011 Annual Report on the Farm
Credit System, at 11, available at https://
E:\FR\FM\22AUR2.SGM
Continued
22AUR2
52288
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 163 / Thursday, August 22, 2013 / Rules and Regulations
tkelley on DSK3SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
cooperatives primarily owned by their
cooperative associations.17 The FCS
banks are regulated and prudentially
supervised by the Farm Credit
Administration (‘‘FCA’’), an
independent agency of the Federal
government.18 The Farm Credit Act
authorizes the banks ‘‘to make loans and
commitments to eligible cooperative
associations.’’ 19 The FCS association
members are, in turn, cooperatives
authorized to make loans to farmers and
ranchers, rural residents, and persons
furnishing farm-related services.20 In
effect, FCS bank cooperatives primarily
make loans to FCS association
cooperatives, which lend to farmers and
ranchers, rural residents, and persons
furnishing farm-related services, and
these borrowers are member-owners of
the FCS associations, which are
member-owners of the FCS banks. In
addition to the example of the FCS
banks, other cooperatives formed under
federal and state laws also have a
similar entity structure in that they are
owned and governed by their members
and they exist to serve those members.
The cooperative exemption, in effect,
provides the end-user exception created
in section 2(h)(7) of the CEA to financial
entity cooperatives when acting in the
interests of their members and in
connection with loans to members. The
exemption benefits the members that
qualify for the end-user exception (or
members that are cooperatives whose
own members qualify for the end-user
exception) because they own and
control the cooperatives, which exist for
the mutual benefit of its members. As
described in greater detail below,21 in
the laws that establish financial
cooperatives as legal entities distinct
from other business structures, Congress
and state legislatures made a policy
determination to facilitate the formation
of cooperatives in order to provide the
cooperative members with the unique
benefits of accessing markets on a
cooperative basis. In this way, financial
cooperatives were created to serve as an
alternative source of capital for their
members. Some of the laws establishing
cooperatives acknowledge that
cooperatives will compete with other
market participants and may have
certain benefits or advantages that are
acceptable for promoting the benefits
www.fca.gov/Download/AnnualReports/
2011AnnualReport.pdf.
17 See 12 U.S.C. 2124(c) (providing that ‘‘[v]oting
stock may be issued or transferred to and held only
by . . . cooperative associations eligible to borrow
from the banks.’’).
18 See id. at 2241.
19 Id. at 2128(a).
20 See id. at 2075.
21 See section IV.
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:26 Aug 21, 2013
Jkt 229001
that members achieve through their
cooperatives.22 Because the
cooperatives are established to serve
their members and the net earnings they
generate through their activities are
returned to those members, the benefits
of the cooperative exemption ultimately
inure to the members of the cooperative.
In the context of required clearing and
the end-user exception, the cooperative
exemption furthers the purpose for
which financial cooperatives were
established, i.e., to act for the mutual
benefit of their members.
III. Comments on the Proposed
Cooperative Exemption Rule
A. Introduction
In proposing an exemption for certain
swaps entered into by certain
cooperatives that are financial entities,
the Commission acknowledged in the
NPRM that central clearing of swaps is
a primary focus of Title VII of the DoddFrank Act. Central clearing mitigates
financial system risks that could result
from swaps and any exemption from
central clearing should be narrowly
drawn to minimize the impact on the
risk mitigation benefits of clearing and
should also be in line with the end-user
exception requirements of section
2(h)(7) of the CEA. Accordingly, the
Commission sought to narrowly tailor
the cooperative exemption by limiting
the types of entities that could elect the
cooperative exemption and the types of
swaps for which the exemption could be
elected.
The Commission received a number
of comment letters both supporting and
opposing the proposed cooperative
exemption. Fourteen rural electric
cooperatives (‘‘Rural Electric
Cooperatives’’) 23 and their trade
association, the National Rural Electric
Cooperative Association (‘‘NRECA’’)
submitted substantially similar
comment letters supporting the
rulemaking. The FCC, the National
Rural Utilities Cooperative Finance
Corporation (‘‘CFC’’),24 the Credit Union
National Association (‘‘CUNA’’), the
22 Id.
23 See Allegheny Electric Cooperative, Inc., Coast
Electric Power Association, Choptank Electric
Cooperative, Claiborne Electric Cooperative, Inc.,
Deaf Smith Electric Cooperative Inc., Dixie Electric
Cooperative, First Electric Cooperative Inc.,
Garkane Energy, Hoosier Energy Rural Electric
Cooperative, Inc., Mountain View Electric
Association, Inc., Pioneer Rural Electric
Cooperative, Inc., Sullivan County Rural Electric
Cooperative, Inc., Sumter Electric Cooperative, Inc.,
and Sunflower Electric Power Corporation.
24 The comment letter from the CFC incorporates,
as an attachment, the signatures of approximately
500 individuals associated with nonprofit rural
electric cooperatives supporting the cooperative
exemption.
PO 00000
Frm 00004
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
American Farm Bureau Federation
(‘‘AFBF’’), Chris Barnard (‘‘Mr.
Barnard’’), and the National Council of
Farmer Cooperatives (‘‘NCFC’’) similarly
supported the proposed cooperative
exemption. Eleven of the twelve Federal
Home Loan Banks (‘‘FHL Banks’’)
submitted a comment letter supporting
the concept of a cooperative exemption
generally, but requested certain changes
to the rule as described below.
The American Bankers Association
(‘‘ABA’’), Lake City Bank, and the
Independent Community Bankers of
America (‘‘ICBA’’) submitted comments
opposing the cooperative exemption on
several grounds. All three opposed the
rule on the grounds that it provides
cooperatives with advantages at the
expense of certain banks. The ABA and
ICBA generally objected to the rule
because they believe the reasoning
behind the proposed rule was faulty and
that the rule making did not comply
with the requirements of section 4(c) of
the CEA and the Administrative
Procedure Act (‘‘APA’’). They also
commented on the efficacy of the costbenefit analysis in the NPRM.
The following discussion first
addresses comments on each paragraph
of the proposed rule followed by a
discussion of the comments addressing
compliance of the proposed rule with
the legal parameters applicable to the
rulemaking under section 4(c) of the
CEA.
B. Regulation 39.6(f)(1) (now § 50.51(a)):
Definition of Exempt Cooperative
The end-user exception is generally
available to entities, including
cooperatives, that are not ‘‘financial
entities,’’ as defined in section
2(h)(7)(C)(i) of the CEA, and entities that
would be financial entities, including
cooperatives, but for the fact that they
meet the requirements of the small
financial institution exemption in
§ 50.50(d). The proposed cooperative
exemption would add an exemption
from required clearing for cooperatives
that do not fall into these two categories
if they meet the definition of ‘‘exempt
cooperative.’’ Proposed § 39.6(f)(1) (now
§ 50.51(a)) defines ‘‘exempt
cooperative’’ to mean a cooperative that
is a ‘‘financial entity’’ solely as defined
in section 2(h)(7)(C)(i)(VIII) of the CEA
for which each member of the
cooperative is either (1) a non-financial
entity, (2) a financial institution to
which the small financial institution
exemption applies, or (3) itself a
cooperative each of whose members fall
into either of the first two categories.
The Commission received a number
of comment letters in support of the
Commission’s rationale provided in the
E:\FR\FM\22AUR2.SGM
22AUR2
tkelley on DSK3SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 163 / Thursday, August 22, 2013 / Rules and Regulations
NPRM for the proposed definition of
exempt cooperative. The Rural Electric
Cooperatives and NRECA agreed with
the Commission’s proposed definition
of ‘‘exempt cooperative’’ and the
Commission’s reasons for establishing
the exemption. The Rural Electric
Cooperatives commented that the
exempt cooperative definition is
appropriate because members of exempt
cooperatives would be eligible for the
end-user exception if entering into
swaps on their own. In their view,
effectively extending the end-user
exception available to the members of
an exempt cooperative to the exempt
cooperative itself is appropriate because
the members act in the financial markets
through the cooperatives that they own.
The FCC, the CFC, CUNA, Mr.
Barnard, and the NCFC similarly
supported the Commission’s definition
of exempt cooperative. Like the Rural
Electric Cooperatives, the FCC suggested
that the ‘‘unique structure of
cooperatives and their relationship to
their member-owners’’ warrants the
cooperative exemption. The CFC and
Mr. Barnard supported the ‘‘passthrough concept’’ embodied in the
cooperative exemption. The FHL Banks
commented that the unique ownership
structure of cooperatives and the fact
that cooperatives act on behalf of
‘‘members that are non-financial
institutions or small financial
institutions’’ justify the Commission
issuing the cooperative exemption.
The ABA and the ICBA submitted
comments opposing the definition of
exempt cooperative because they
believe there is no policy justification
for the exemption and that the
Commission’s reasons for the exemption
are not analytically appropriate. They
commented that cooperatives do not
play a unique role and are not
themselves unique. The ABA suggested
the Commission ignored the ‘‘fact that
banks perform the same functions for
customers that cooperatives perform for
their members.’’ Similarly, the ICBA
commented that the Commission has
not described how exempt cooperatives
differ from commercial banks.
According to ICBA, ‘‘community banks
play the same role on behalf of their
customers’’ that cooperatives play when
facing the larger financial markets on
behalf of their members. Both the ABA
and the ICBA also noted that banks
enter into swaps to hedge risks. The
ABA noted that almost one-third of all
the loans made by the FCS did not
involve individual farmers or ranchers.
According to the ICBA, smaller
‘‘community’’ banks should be given the
‘‘same exemption as any financial
cooperative of the same or larger size.’’
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:26 Aug 21, 2013
Jkt 229001
The ICBA and the ABA requested that
‘‘smaller’’ banks, with assets above the
$10 billion threshold in the end-user
exception, be exempted from mandatory
clearing along with cooperatives.
In response, the Commission does not
disagree with these comments to the
extent that banks often provide the same
services to their customers that exempt
cooperatives provide to their members.
However, the nature of the services
provided by cooperatives to their
members is not the rationale for the
cooperative exemption. The
Commission’s rationale is based in large
part on the relationship between a
cooperative and its members, which is
different from the relationship between
banks and their customers. The
cooperative exemption in effect
provides the end-user exception created
in section 2(h)(7) of the CEA to entities
whose members themselves qualify for
the end-user exception, but would
otherwise not be able to realize the full
effects of the exception when those
members act in the financial markets
through their member-owned exempt
cooperatives that do not qualify for the
small financial institution exemption.
The rule benefits the members who
qualify for the end-user exception
through the cooperatives that they own
and control and exist for their mutual
benefit. Because the cooperatives are
established to serve their members and
the net earnings they generate through
their activities are returned to those
members, the benefits of the cooperative
exemption ultimately inure to the
members of the cooperative.
The Commission notes that the
definition of ‘‘exempt cooperative’’ is
narrowly tailored so that only a
cooperative for which each of its
members individually, or if it has
members that are cooperatives, each of
the members of those cooperatives
individually, would qualify for the enduser exception would qualify for the
cooperative exemption. Furthermore,
§ 39.6(f)(2) (now § 50.51(b)) provides
that the exemption is only available for
swaps executed in connection with
originating member loans and swaps
that hedge or mitigate risk related to
loans to members or arising from certain
swaps with members. As such, under
the final rule, an exempt cooperative
shall not elect the exemption for swaps
related to non-member activity of the
cooperative.
Exempt cooperatives are distinct from
banks not because of the services they
offer, but because they exist to serve
their members’ interests and act as
intermediaries for their members in the
marketplace. The member-owners
generally are the customers of the
PO 00000
Frm 00005
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
52289
cooperatives and the Commission
drafted the proposed rule to be available
only to the extent the cooperative
exemption is used in connection with
member-related activities. Cooperatives
are owned by their members and as
such, their governing bodies generally
consist of members. Their net earnings
are returned to their members either
through rebates or distributions, often
referred to as ‘‘patronage,’’ or are
retained by the cooperatives as capital
to be used to provide services to
members. For example, the FCC noted
in its comments that FCS cooperatives
were established by federal law to
operate for the benefit of farmerowners.25 The FCC further noted that by
law, each cooperative association in the
FCS has a board of directors comprised
of voting members of the association,
and as required by law, at least one
‘‘outside’’ director.26 Furthermore,
voting stock may only be held by
farmers, ranchers, producers of aquatic
products, and cooperative associations
eligible to borrow from FCS
institutions.27 Each owner of association
voting stock is entitled to one vote in
the affairs of the association, regardless
of the amount of the stock held.28 FCS
additionally commented that each year
FCS cooperatives pay patronage to their
members, both in cash and allocated
equity.29 Furthermore, unlike for-profit
entities that generally pay out dividends
based on the amount of stock purchased
by each investor, as discussed in greater
detail below, cooperatives generally pay
out or allocate earnings to the memberowners based on the amount of business
25 The FCC cited Section 1.1(a) of the Farm Credit
Act (12 U.S.C. 2001) (‘‘farmer-owned cooperative
Farm Credit System’’) and Section 1.1(b) thereof (‘‘It
is the objective of this chapter to continue to
encourage farmer- and rancher-borrowers
participation in the management, control, and
ownership of a permanent system of credit for
agriculture which will be responsive to the credit
needs of all types of agricultural producers having
a basis for credit, and to modernize and improve the
authorizations and means for furnishing such credit
and credit for housing in rural areas made available
through the institutions constituting the Farm
Credit System as herein provided.’’).
26 12 U.S.C. 2072.
27 12 U.S.C. 2154a(c)(1)(D)(i).
28 12 CFR 611.350.
29 For example, in 2011, FCS institutions
distributed about $903 million in cash patronage
and $243 million in stock patronage to the
approximately 489,000 system shareholders. Farm
Credit Admin., 2011 Annual Report on the Farm
Credit System, 18 (2011); Press Release, Fed. Farm
Credit Banks Funding Corp., Farm Credit System
Reports Net Income of $3.940 Billion for 2011, 5
(Feb. 17, 2012), available at https://
www.farmcreditfunding.com/farmcredit/serve/
public/pressre/finin/report.pdf?assetId=198426.
E:\FR\FM\22AUR2.SGM
22AUR2
52290
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 163 / Thursday, August 22, 2013 / Rules and Regulations
tkelley on DSK3SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
undertaken by each member with the
cooperative.30
On the other hand, banks generally
are for-profit, publicly or privately held
corporations whose investor-owners are
not required to be the users of the bank’s
services, and often are not. The
governing bodies of banks, like other
for-profit entities, are typically elected
by the shareholders whose voting power
is determined by the amount of common
stock each investor owns. A board of
directors of a corporation has a legal
duty to the corporation and the
shareholders and, accordingly, must
consider shareholder value in its
actions.31 As such, unlike the memberfocused purposes of exempt
cooperatives, a primary purpose of
banks is to generate value for their
owners, who generally are not their
customers. The mission of a cooperative
is to act in the interests of its members,
while the goal of a for-profit business,
whatever its size, is to benefit the
owners of that business, which are not
necessarily its customers. Unlike a
cooperative, which is an extension of its
members as a business matter, a bank is
not an extension of its customers.
Accordingly, the Commission believes
the rationale for extending the end-user
exception to cooperatives does not
apply to banks in the same way.
The ICBA further questioned whether
‘‘members’’ are any different from
‘‘customers,’’ because, in the case of the
FCS, borrowers can be considered
owners or members even if they do not
put their own capital into the
organization. For example, according to
the ICBA, an FCS borrower can become
a member by paying an additional
$1,000 on a loan or one percent of the
loan value, whichever is less.
The FCC commented that the Farm
Credit Act and related regulations
prescribe minimum stock purchase
requirements for FCS borrowers and
also require that FCS institutions meet
minimum capital standards well in
excess of the amount of purchased
stock, citing 12 U.S.C. 2151. The FCC
noted that as of December 31, 2011,
combined FCS association capital was
over $24 billion dollars, or 19% of
outstanding loans. Furthermore, the FCS
noted that ‘‘[v]irtually all that capital is
the result of income earned and
retained.’’
The Commission believes that the
comments of the ICBA and FCC on this
issue further demonstrate the
uniqueness of the member-owner
relationship between exempt
cooperatives and their members and
how the cooperatives are, in effect,
extensions of their members acting in
the interests of their members in a way
that is not the case for the relationship
between other types of financial
institutions and their customers. The
earnings retained by FCS cooperatives
would otherwise be paid out to
members pro rata based on the amount
of borrowing from the cooperatives. As
such, a cooperative member has a
vested, pro rata interest in its
cooperative based on the amount of
business the member does with the
cooperative. While a for-profit entity
such as a bank also may retain capital,
the capital, if paid out to the owners,
would be paid to the equity investors,
not the customers of the entity and not
based on the amount of business the
customers do with the entity.
The ICBA and the ABA further
commented that some of the entities
that the cooperatives are ‘‘standing in
the marketplace on behalf of’’ are
sophisticated entities and are capable of
entering into the swap marketplace on
their own and do not need a cooperative
to face the market. The ICBA also
commented that all of the component
entities of cooperatives would have ‘‘no
trouble arranging financing from private
sector sources.’’
The Commission did not assert in the
NPRM that the members of cooperatives
could only access financial markets
through the cooperatives or that sole
access through cooperatives was a
reason for the proposed rule. Rather, the
Commission recognized that certain
entities for which the end-user
exception is available have traditionally
accessed the markets through financial
cooperatives that they own and which
exist for their benefit. For example, this
relationship is well established and is
codified into the federal law that created
the FCS.32 If the cooperative exemption
were not adopted by the Commission,
these entities would not be able to both
continue to use their cooperatives and
receive the full benefit of the end-user
30 See 18 a.m. Jur. 2d Cooperative Associations
§ 19 (2012) (‘‘Ordinarily, the profits of a cooperative
association are distributed to its members in the
form of patronage refunds or dividends in amounts
determined by the use made of the association
facilities by the patrons, and statutes frequently so
provide.’’).
31 See, e.g., 18B Am. Jur. 2d Corporations 1460
(2012).
32 ‘‘It is declared to be the policy of the Congress
. . . that the farmer-owned cooperative [FCS] be
designed to accomplish the objective of improving
the income and well-being of American farmers and
ranchers by furnishing sound, adequate, and
constructive credit and closely related services to
them, their cooperatives, and to selected farmrelated businesses necessary for efficient farm
operations.’’ 12 U.S.C. 2001(a).
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:26 Aug 21, 2013
Jkt 229001
PO 00000
Frm 00006
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
exception created in the Dodd-Frank
Act.
The ICBA questioned the
Commission’s statement in the preamble
to the proposed cooperative exemption
that ‘‘cooperatives exist to serve their
member-owners and do not act for their
own profit.’’ The ICBA commented that
the FCS, credit unions and other
cooperatives ‘‘pay their executives
millions of dollars each year.’’
The ICBA, Lake City Bank, and ABA
also noted that the FCS and credit
unions and other cooperatives that
would be able to use the cooperative
exemption already enjoy a number of
significant advantages, such as low-cost
funding, tax exemptions, and, in some
cases, government sponsored enterprise
(‘‘GSE’’) status. They expressed concern
that providing credit unions, FCS
cooperatives, and other cooperatives
with an exemption from mandatory
clearing would ‘‘exacerbate their
competitive advantage over banks.’’
Furthermore, the ICBA stated that ‘‘FCS
lenders have in recent years positioned
themselves to act almost identically to
banks through deposit taking
arrangements, credit card offerings,
check writing capabilities and outright
illegitimate activities granted by their
permissive regulator.’’
The Commission is not responsible
for the creation, administration, or
implementation of those legal
characteristics of cooperatives referred
to in the comments as being
‘‘competitive advantages.’’ These
characteristics, by and large, flow from
policies enacted by Congress or state
legislatures. Further, the Commission is
not the regulator responsible for the
laws and regulations referred to by
commenters that govern cooperatives.
The Commission has determined
without regard to such other asserted
benefits for cooperatives, to offer an
elective clearing exemption to entities
qualifying as exempt cooperatives to
extend the full benefits of the end-user
exception established in the Dodd-Frank
Act to entities that would qualify for
that exception, but which choose to act
through their cooperatives in the
financial marketplace.33
Comments regarding the
compensation of executives are outside
the scope of this rulemaking. The
rationale for the cooperative exemption
is based on the member-owner structure
of cooperatives, not on how much
executives are paid or whether that pay
is fair. The Commission defers to the
regulators who enforce those regulations
33 For a discussion of the related ‘‘fair
competition’’ provision in section 4(c), see section
IV herein.
E:\FR\FM\22AUR2.SGM
22AUR2
tkelley on DSK3SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 163 / Thursday, August 22, 2013 / Rules and Regulations
for issues related to executive
compensation.
With respect to swaps, the ICBA
noted that cooperatives and community
banks both enter into swaps to hedge
the interest rate risk of loans to their
customers or members. The ICBA
suggested that swaps hedging the
underlying risks of loans to customers
pose the same lower risk to the financial
system that the FCC claims regarding
swaps hedging the risks of loans to its
cooperative members.
The Commission notes that it is not
relying on the assertion by the FCC that
swaps related to hedging loans to
cooperative members may be less risky
than other types of swaps that financial
entities may undertake as a primary
reason for distinguishing exempt
cooperatives from other types of lending
entities.34 As explained in the NPRM,
the potential lower risk of such swaps
is, however, one of the reasons why the
Commission is restricting the
cooperative exemption to swaps related
to member loans.
The National Association of Federal
Credit Unions requested that the
Commission specify that the cooperative
exemption applies to ‘‘all credit
unions.’’ The Commission clarifies that
the exemption applies to all
cooperatives, including credit unions
that meet the definition of ‘‘exempt
cooperative’’ in the final rule. The
Commission does not have enough
information to determine whether ‘‘all
credit unions’’ are eligible for the
exemption. Whether any particular
credit union meets the definition of an
exempt cooperative will depend on the
relevant facts and circumstances for that
credit union.
The FHL Banks stated that they would
not qualify as exempt cooperatives
because each FHL Bank has one or more
members that are financial institutions
that do not qualify for the small
financial institution exemption. The
FHL Banks commented that the
cooperative exemption, as proposed,
would ‘‘unfairly and arbitrarily’’
penalize members of a cooperative that
would qualify as small financial
institutions under the end-user
exception if the cooperative also has one
or more large financial institutions as
members. The FHL Banks stated that
this would result in the inconsistent
treatment of two similarly situated
entities. The FHL Banks also point to
the joint final rule on the definition of
the term ‘‘swap dealer,’’ where the
34 The Commission believes, however, that
because exempt cooperatives serve their members
and are controlled by their members, it can be
expected that cooperatives will focus their swap
activity on member loan-related activities.
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:26 Aug 21, 2013
Jkt 229001
Securities and Exchange Commission
along with the Commission excluded all
swaps between a cooperative and its
members from the analysis of whether
that cooperative is an SD. This
regulatory treatment, according to the
FHL Banks, would be ‘‘consistent’’ with
the Commission allowing the FHL
Banks to elect the cooperative
exemption in certain circumstances.
The FHL Banks requested that the
Commission remove the limitation that
bars a cooperative from being an
‘‘exempt cooperative’’ if it has one or
more members that are financial entities
that are not themselves cooperatives
with members that qualify for the enduser exception. Instead, the FHL Banks
suggested that the Commission allow
cooperatives to enter into swaps that
hedge or mitigate commercial risk
related to loans to ‘‘qualified members’’
or arising from swaps entered into with
‘‘qualified members’’ that are eligible for
the end-user exception. The FHL Banks
proposed the term ‘‘qualified member’’
to mean a member of an exempt
cooperative that is (1) not a financial
entity, (2) a financial entity that is
exempt from the definition of financial
entity under the small financial
institution exemption in § 50.50(d), or
(3) a cooperative, each member of which
is not a financial entity or is exempt
from mandatory clearing because it
qualifies for the small financial
institution exemption. The FHL Banks
commented that their proposed
approach is consistent with the DoddFrank Act’s objective of mandating that
swaps entered into in connection with
or for large financial institutions be
cleared, without penalizing small
financial institutions. According to the
FHL Banks, their proposed revisions to
the cooperative exemption would allow
FHL Banks to qualify as an ‘‘exempt
cooperative,’’ in appropriate situations.
The FHL Banks also stated that this
revised cooperative exemption would
apply to less than 10% of the
outstanding notional amount of the FHL
Banks’ swaps. The ICBA, like the FHL
Banks, suggested that the Commission
revise the definition of exempt
cooperative to not exclude the FHL
Banks ‘‘to the extent that they engage in
swaps for the benefit of their members
who individually qualify as small
financial institutions.’’
In response to the FHL Banks’ and the
ICBA’s comments regarding
cooperatives that are ineligible for the
cooperative exemption because they
have one or more financial entity
members, the Commission declines to
extend the exemption beyond the
parameters as proposed. The
Commission disagrees with the FHL
PO 00000
Frm 00007
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
52291
Banks’ assertion that the cooperative
exemption is arbitrary or unfair to
financial institutions that qualify for the
small financial institution exemption.
Under § 39.6(f)(1)(iii)(A) (now
§ 50.51(a)(3)(i)) of the proposed rule,
small financial institutions that meet the
definition thereof in § 50.50(d) can be
members of exempt cooperatives. These
members can include banks, savings
associations, FCS institutions, or credit
unions, so long as each of them qualifies
as a small financial institution under
§ 50.50(d) (i.e. the institution has total
assets of $10 billion or less). They
would be treated in the same way as all
other entities that may qualify for the
end-user exception, and therefore can be
members of exempt cooperatives as
defined.
Furthermore, as the Commission
acknowledged above and in the NPRM,
it is concerned that exemptions from the
clearing requirement could detract from
the systemic risk reducing benefits of
clearing. This is particularly a concern
if the exemption could be elected for
swaps that relate to risks of entities that
Congress clearly intended to be subject
to the clearing requirement—financial
entities as defined in section 2(h)(7)(C)
of the CEA that are not expressly
exempted from that definition. As such,
the Commission narrowed the
cooperative exemption to apply solely
to a cooperative whose members (or if
it has members that are cooperatives,
the members of those cooperatives)
could themselves elect the end-user
exception.
The importance of a narrow
cooperative exemption is apparent
when considering the possible effect of
broadening the exemption in the
manner requested by the FHL Banks and
ICBA. A fundamental characteristic of
cooperatives is that they distribute or
allocate the patronage earnings of the
cooperative, i.e., the excess of a
cooperative’s revenues over its costs
arising from transactions done with or
for its members,35 to each member based
on the amount of patronage by the
member, i.e., proportionally based on
the amount of business each member
does with the cooperative.36
Accordingly, even if a cooperative with
financial entity members only elected
35 See
FASB ASC 905–10–05.
distribution or allocation of patronage
earnings to the members based on the amount of
business they do with the cooperative is a guiding
principle of cooperatives and is a necessary element
for a cooperative to claim a deduction for taxation
purposes under federal law. See Donald A.
Frederick, Income Tax Treatment of Cooperatives:
Background, Cooperative Information Report 44,
Part 1, 2005 Ed. (April 2005) at 50, citing, Puget
Sound Plywood, Inc. v. Commissioner, 44 T.C. 305,
308 (1965).
36 The
E:\FR\FM\22AUR2.SGM
22AUR2
52292
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 163 / Thursday, August 22, 2013 / Rules and Regulations
tkelley on DSK3SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
the cooperative exemption for swaps
related to loans to members that qualify
for the end-user exception, a portion of
the financial benefits from those swaps
in the form of higher net income may
shift from the qualifying small members
to the larger members as part of the full
member pro rata patronage distribution
or allocation. Furthermore, the risks of
such swaps because they are noncleared could also negatively impact the
large financial institution members to
the extent that the net income of the
cooperative is negatively impacted.
As an example, consider the relative
amounts of lending by the FHL Banks to
those of their largest members that do
not qualify for the end-user exception as
compared to the FHL Banks’ lending to
their other members. The 12 FHL Banks
had 7,774 members as of the end of
2011.37 Each of the 12 FHL Banks
reported the amount of lending business
they did with their five largest members
in the 2011 Combined Financial Report
for the FHL Banks. In 2011, $222.6
billion of the $403.3 billion lent by the
FHL Banks to their members was lent to
the largest five members of each of the
12 FHL Banks.38 Of those 60 large
members, approximately 49 had total
assets in excess of $10 billion.39 The
amount loaned to those 49 members was
about $212.7 billion, or 53% of the
dollar amount lent by the FHL Banks.
Furthermore, those 49 members do not
include all members of the FHL Banks
with assets greater than $10 billion.
Accordingly, the Commission estimates
the percentage of lending by the FHL
Banks to members that cannot qualify
for the end-user exception was higher
than 53% of total lending in 2011.40 If
37 FHL Banks, Combined Financial Report for the
Year Ended December 31, 2011 (issued March 29,
2012) at 43, available at https://www.fhlb-of.com/
ofweb_userWeb/resources/11yrend.pdf.
38 Id. at 44–45. The Commission arrived at the
$222.6 billion amount by adding together the loan
values of the 60 individual members listed in the
Combined Financial Report of the FHL Banks.
39 The Commission estimated this number by
reviewing publically available information related
to the assets of each of the 60 members, such as
members’ annual 10–K financial reports filed with
the SEC (available on the SEC’s Web site and posted
on the members’ Web sites), other annual financial
reports and information, such as press releases
posted on members’ Web sites, and reports
published by the Federal Reserve and Federal
Deposit Insurance Corporation. As an example, the
Commission reviewed the Federal Reserve’s
Statistical Release for Large Banks, which provided
information regarding the total assets held by 27 of
the 60 members. See Federal Reserve, Statistical
Release for Large Banks, available at https://
www.federalreserve.gov/releases/lbr/current/
default.htm.
40 The FHL Banks Combined Financial Report for
the Year Ended December 31, 2011, does not break
down lending amount for every member. The 49
members used in the Commission’s calculations do
not include all members of the FHL Banks with
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:26 Aug 21, 2013
Jkt 229001
the FHL Banks were able to use the
cooperative exemption, under the
cooperative structure in which
patronage benefits are allocated pro rata
based on the amount of business each
member does with the cooperative, a
significant portion of the benefits and
risks from the election of the exemption
could spread to the large financial entity
members. This would also be the case
even if the exemption were only
available to swaps related to small
financial institutions because the
distribution of patronage to the
members is based to a large degree on
the amount of borrowing by each
member.
Similarly, the Commission is
concerned that allowing cooperatives
with members that do not qualify for the
end-user exception to elect the
cooperative exemption could open up
avenues for abuse of the exemption and
evasion of clearing. For example, larger
financial entities could form
cooperatives capitalized by the large
financial entities, but which also
include small affiliates or trading
partners of the larger financial entities
that would qualify as small financial
institutions. They could then use these
cooperatives to shift their borrowing
and swap needs between the large and
small entities to be able to take
advantage of the cooperative exception
in ways that benefit the larger
institutions. The Commission considers
these risks of abuse of the exemption
and evasion of the clearing requirement
warrant limiting the definition of
exempt cooperative as written. The
Commission notes that small financial
institutions can elect the end-user
exception themselves.
The ICBA noted that the Dodd-Frank
Act’s requirement that the Commission
consider exempting small financial
institutions is not necessarily limited to
institutions with less than $10 billion in
total assets. The ICBA commented that
there are 36 ‘‘community banks’’ 41 with
assets over $10 billion, and within the
category of ‘‘community banks,’’ the
asset sizes of those banks range from
$10.5 billion to $50 billion. The ICBA
suggested that the asset size test in the
end-user exception be increased up to
$50 billion or that community banks be
given a ‘‘ride along’’ provision so that
assets greater than $10 billion. Accordingly, while
the total percentage of lending to financial entities
with total assets greater than $10 billion cannot be
calculated based on the information available in the
financial report, it is likely significantly higher than
the 53% calculated for the 49 members with over
$10 billion in total assets for which lending
information is available.
41 The ICBA did not specifically define the term
‘‘community banks’’ other than by reference to the
$50 billion maximum asset level.
PO 00000
Frm 00008
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
community banks that do not qualify for
the end-user exception could elect the
same exemption as cooperatives.
With these comments, the ICBA is
effectively asking the Commission to
reopen and revise the end-user
exception rule as applied to financial
institutions generally. The Commission
set forth the reasons for the $10 billion
total asset limit for small financial
institutions in the end-user exception
rulemaking and believes that those
reasons remain appropriate. This
rulemaking addresses the specific issue
of whether an exemption from clearing
should be granted to certain
cooperatives—including the issue of
whether there are relevant differences
between the covered cooperatives and
private banks—and is not intended as a
vehicle for reopening the end-user
exception regulations.
C. Regulation 39.6(f)(2) (now § 50.51(b)):
Swaps to Which the Cooperative
Exemption Applies
Proposed § 39.6(f)(2) (now 50.51(b))
limits application of the cooperative
exemption to swaps entered into with
members of the exempt cooperative in
connection with originating loans 42 for
members or swaps entered into by
exempt cooperatives that hedge or
mitigate risks related to loans to
members or arising from member loanrelated swaps. This provision assures
that the cooperative exemption is used
only for swaps related to member
lending activities. Since the definition
of an exempt cooperative requires that
all members be entities who can elect
the end-user exception or cooperatives
all of whose members can, this
condition assures that the exemption
will benefit entities who could
themselves elect the end-user exception
and can be used for swaps that hedge or
mitigate risk in connection with
member loans and swaps as would be
required by section 2(h)(7)(A)(ii) of the
CEA.
The primary rationale for the
cooperative exemption is based on the
unique relationship between
cooperatives and their member-owners.
Expanding this exemption to include
swaps related to non-member activities
would extend the exemption beyond its
intended purpose. Furthermore,
allowing cooperatives to enter into noncleared swaps with non-member
borrowers, or swaps that serve purposes
other than hedging member loans or
42 The phrase ‘‘in connection with originating a
loan’’ is similarly used in the definition of swap
dealer in § 1.3(ggg) of the Commission’s
Regulations. See 77 FR 30596, 30744 (May 23,
2012). That meaning is incorporated in the final
rule.
E:\FR\FM\22AUR2.SGM
22AUR2
tkelley on DSK3SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 163 / Thursday, August 22, 2013 / Rules and Regulations
swaps, would give the cooperatives,
which are large financial entities, an
exception from regulatory requirements
that would not be provided to other
market participants engaging in such
similar business with respect to nonmembers that is not justified by their
cooperative structure or the provisions
of the Dodd-Frank Act.
The CFC commented that it agrees
with the types of swaps eligible for the
cooperative exemption described by the
Commission in the preamble of the
NPRM. The CFC stated that the use of
the phrase ‘‘related to’’ in the rule text
is consistent with the ‘‘pass-through
concept’’ that underlies the cooperative
exemption. The FCC suggested that the
Commission provide additional clarity
on the ‘‘related to’’ standard. The FCC
commented that the ‘‘related to’’
standard should be broad enough to
cover swaps that hedge or mitigate risk
related to ‘‘interest rate, liquidity, and
balance sheet risks’’ associated with a
cooperative’s lending business. The FCC
pointed to the statement in the preamble
to the proposed rule that explained that
the ‘‘related to’’ test involves hedging or
mitigating risks ‘‘associated with’’
member loans. The FCC supported this
interpretation. The FCC requested that
the Commission clarify that certain
types of transactions would be covered
by the cooperative exemption.
Specifically, the FCC suggested that the
following swaps should be covered by
the cooperative exemption: (1) Swaps
managing interest rate, liquidity, and
balance sheet risk, (2) swaps qualifying
as GAAP hedges of bonds and floating
rate notes, and (3) swaps hedging FCS
banks’ liquidity reserves that are
required by the FCA.
The AFBF also requested that the
Commission clarify that swaps
mitigating or hedging balance sheet,
interest rate, and liquidity risks
associated with their cooperative
lending business are eligible for the
cooperative exemption.
The Commission’s rationale for the
cooperative exemption is based on the
unique relationship between a
cooperative and its members. The
primary purpose for the cooperative
exemption is to, in effect, provide the
full benefits of the end-user exception
created in section 2(h)(7) of the CEA to
entities that qualify for the end-user
exception, but otherwise do not receive
the full benefits of the exception if they
use their cooperatives as their
intermediary in the markets as they
have traditionally done. Thus, the
Commission will interpret this
exemption to ensure that the exemption
is only used for swaps that are
undertaken to directly further the
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:26 Aug 21, 2013
Jkt 229001
interests of the members who are
themselves eligible for the end-user
exception. Accordingly, the
Commission declines to expand the
types of transactions eligible for the
exemption beyond those swaps that are
entered into in connection with
originating a loan or loans for a member,
or swaps that hedge or mitigate
commercial risk related to loans with
members, or hedge or mitigate the
commercial risk associated with a swap
between an exempt cooperative and its
members in connection with originating
loans to members.
With respect to the comments of the
AFBF and the FCC regarding swaps that
hedge balance sheet, interest rate, and
liquidity risks associated with their
cooperative lending business, the
Commission reiterates that only those
swaps relating to member loans are
eligible for the exemption, not swaps
related to a cooperative’s entire lending
business to the extent that lending
business includes loans to nonmembers. Accordingly, the exemption
may be used for swaps that hedge
balance sheet, interest rate, and
liquidity risks, but only limited to the
extent those risks are related to loans
made by the cooperative to its members.
The Commission is concerned that
without this limitation, cooperatives
could use this exemption for risks
related to non-member-based activities,
which would be inconsistent with the
general rationale for the exemption and
could result in a competitive benefit to
eligible cooperatives that is also
inconsistent with the Commission’s
rationale for the exemption.
As the text of § 39.6(f)(2)(i) (now
§ 50.51(b)(1)) provides, the phrase
‘‘swap is entered into with a member of
the exempt cooperative in connection
with originating a loan or loans for the
member’’ should be read consistent with
17 CFR 1.3(ggg)(5). Among other things,
17 CFR 1.3(ggg)(5) provides that an
acceptable swap includes a swap with
members for which the rate, asset,
liability or other notional item
underlying such swap is, or is directly
related to, a financial term of such loan,
which includes, without limitation, the
loan’s duration, rate of interest, the
currency or currencies in which it is
made and its principal amount; or the
swap is required, as a condition of the
loan under the exempt cooperative’s
loan underwriting criteria, to be in place
in order to hedge price risks incidental
to the borrower’s business and arising
from potential changes in the price of a
commodity (other than an excluded
commodity).
Section 39.6(f)(2)(ii) (now
§ 50.51(b)(2)) also includes in the
PO 00000
Frm 00009
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
52293
cooperative exemption swaps that hedge
or mitigate risk related to loans to
members or arising from a swap or
swaps with members entered into
pursuant to § 39.6(f)(2)(i) (now
§ 50.51(b)(1)). This provision includes
swaps that the exempt cooperatives may
enter into with non-members to hedge
or mitigate the risks incurred by the
cooperatives related to their member
lending activities. Such swaps can
include swaps entered into with nonmember parties (e.g., SDs) to hedge or
mitigate risks such as interest rate risk
related to funding loans to fund member
loans, or liquidity or balance sheet risks,
so long as those liquidity and balance
sheet risks arise from activities related
to member loans.
As discussed above in this section,
the risks must be related to member
loans only. For example, the
Commission understands that
cooperatives sometimes issue bonds or
enter into wholesale funding
transactions to fund member and nonmember loans. The cooperative
exemption would permit an exemption
for swaps, such as interest rate swaps or
interest rate caps, used to hedge those
funding transactions, but only to the
extent that the interest rate swaps or
interest rate caps relate to memberassociated loans. Only swaps hedging or
mitigating risk arising from the portion
of the bonds or wholesale funding
proceeds that is related to, or is
expected to be related to, direct loans to
members are eligible for the exemption.
Practically speaking, this means that for
a cooperative borrowing on a wholesale
basis for both member and non-memberassociated loans, the aggregate notional
amount of any non-cleared swaps
hedging the wholesale funding loans
must not exceed the aggregate principal
value of the wholesale funding loans
less the aggregate principal amount lent
or expected to be lent to non-members.
Cooperatives would need to adjust that
aggregate notional amount by
termination or other means as soon as
practicable if that aggregate amount is
exceeded during the life of any such
swaps.
As another example, eligible
cooperatives may want to hedge interest
rate risk associated with a portfolio of
loans to multiple borrowers with one or
more swaps. If the loan portfolio being
hedged consists solely of loans to
members, then the cooperative
exemption would be available for those
hedging swaps if the requirements of
§ 39.6(f) (now § 50.51) are met.
However, if the cooperative has nonmember loans in the loan portfolio
being hedged, then the swap may be
hedging risk that is not related to
E:\FR\FM\22AUR2.SGM
22AUR2
tkelley on DSK3SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
52294
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 163 / Thursday, August 22, 2013 / Rules and Regulations
member loans and, if so, the exemption
would not be available for that swap. In
order to be able to elect the exemption
for swaps that hedge a portfolio of
member loans and non-member loans,
the aggregate notional amount of any
such swaps must not exceed the
aggregate principal amount of the
member loans in the portfolio.
Cooperatives would need to adjust that
notional amount by termination or other
means, such as clearing certain swaps,
as soon as practicable if that amount is
exceeded during the life of any such
swap. The same limitation applies to
balance sheet risks. The exemption may
be elected for swaps hedging balance
sheet risks only to the extent they arise
from member loan related activity. For
example, balance sheet risks could be
hedged with swaps for which the
cooperative exemption may be available
to the extent that the aggregate notional
amount of such swaps does not exceed
the aggregate principal amount of
member loans.
With respect to FCC’s comments
relating to ‘‘liquidity reserves’’ required
by the FCA, the Commission believes
the same general approach described
above should apply. That is, swaps
hedging risks related to liquidity
reserves may be eligible for the
exemption only to the extent that such
reserves being hedged are related to
member loans. For example, if a
cooperative makes loans to both
members and non-members and hedges
risks related to liquidity reserves for the
combined loan portfolio, the
cooperative would be permitted to elect
the exemption for the hedging swaps to
the extent that the aggregate notional
amount of the swaps does not exceed an
amount equal to the total liquidity
reserves multiplied by the proportion of
the member loans principal amount to
the total principal amount of member
loans and non-member loans in the
cooperative’s combined loan portfolio.
The CFC commented that the
Commission should modify the
language of section 39.6(f)(2)(ii) (now
§ 50.51(b)(2)), which is a cross-reference
to the definition of hedging or
mitigating commercial risk for the
purposes of the end-user exception, to
replace the term ‘‘commercial
enterprise’’ with the term ‘‘exempt
cooperative.’’
The requested change is not
necessary. As explained in the final
release for the end-user exception,43 the
use of the term ‘‘commercial enterprise’’
is intended to refer to the underlying
activity to which the risk being hedged
or mitigated relates in the context of the
43 77
FR 42572 (July 19, 2012).
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:26 Aug 21, 2013
Jkt 229001
entity’s normal business activities, not
simply the type of entity claiming the
exemption. For example, in the context
of the cooperative exemption, it would
include the risks undertaken by a
cooperative in the normal course of
business of providing loans to members.
D. Regulation 39.6(f)(3) (now § 50.51(c)):
Reporting
The Commission believes it is
appropriate to impose certain reporting
requirements on any entities that may
be exempted from the clearing
requirement by this regulation. The
reporting requirements in the final rule
are effectively identical to the reporting
requirements for the end-user exception.
For purposes of regulatory consistency,
§ 39.6(f)(3) (now § 50.51(c)) incorporates
the provisions of § 50.50(b) with only
those changes needed to apply the
reporting provisions in the specific
context of the cooperative exemption.
Regulation 50.50(b) requires one of the
counterparties (the ‘‘reporting
counterparty’’) to provide, or cause to be
provided, to a registered SDR, or if no
registered SDR is available, to the
Commission, information about how the
counterparty electing the exception
generally expects to meet its financial
obligations associated with non-cleared
swaps. In addition, § 50.50(b) requires
reporting of certain information that the
Commission will use to monitor
compliance with, and prevent abuse of,
the exception. The reporting
counterparty would be required to
provide the information at the time the
electing counterparty elects the
cooperative exemption.
The CUNA requested that the
Commission minimize the compliance
burdens on cooperatives that elect to
use the cooperative exemption,
including the notification requirement.
The ICBA requested that the
Commission modify the reporting
requirement when the cooperative
exemption is elected. The ICBA
commented that the aggregate reporting
requirements of § 50.50(b) do not allow
the Commission to ‘‘monitor actual risks
or swaps usage.’’ The ICBA stated that
it was concerned that FCS members
actively seek to lend to a number of
entities that are not owners of the FCS.
Because of this, the Commission,
according to the ICBA, would not have
a way of verifying that the swaps for
which an FCS bank elected this
exemption are actually eligible for the
cooperative exemption. Neither the
ICBA nor the CUNA proposed any
specific changes to the rule text in
connection with their comments.
The Commission has determined not
to change the reporting requirements
PO 00000
Frm 00010
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
proposed in § 39.6(f)(3) (now § 50.51(c))
and to keep them consistent with the
reporting requirements of the end-user
exception. The Commission discussed
at length in the final release of the enduser exception how the reporting
requirements for entities electing the
clearing requirement exception are
simplified through a check-the-box
approach and can be reported along
with the other reporting required for all
swaps under the Commission’s part 45
regulations.44 The Commission believes
that the reporting requirements will
provide the Commission with sufficient
information, along with the other
information to be reported for all swaps
and information publicly reported by
cooperatives, to detect evasion of
required clearing or abuse of the
exemption. For example, every swap
executed by a cooperative, as is the case
with all swaps, must be reported to an
SDR or to the Commission and the
parties to that swap will be identified.
Accordingly, the Commission will be
able to review and analyze the economic
and other details of all swaps entered
into by each cooperative. As such, the
Commission is able to monitor actual
swap usage by cooperatives. The swap
reporting requirements are not intended
to monitor the risk levels of individual
cooperatives. Monitoring the
accumulated risk undertaken by
financial cooperatives is generally the
purview of their supervisory regulators.
Based on a review of publicly
available information and discussions
with the regulators of financial
cooperatives, the Commission believes
that a large majority of lending by these
cooperatives is to their members. As
such, at present there do not appear to
be substantial incentives for
cooperatives to abuse the exemption
with respect to swaps that are not
member related. Notwithstanding the
foregoing, the limitations on using the
exemption for non-member related
activities is clearly established in the
final rule and the Commission is
confident that the tools available to the
Commission for addressing abuse or
evasion of the cooperative exemption
are sufficient without changing the
reporting requirements as proposed.
E. Other Comments on the Proposed
Rule
The ABA and the ICBA commented
that the FCS, as a GSE, presents a
significant risk for the U.S. taxpayer.
The ICBA stated that the FCS was
‘‘bailed out’’ by the government during
the farm credit crisis in the 1980s. The
ABA and the ICBA noted that the FCS,
44 77
E:\FR\FM\22AUR2.SGM
FR at 42565–70.
22AUR2
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 163 / Thursday, August 22, 2013 / Rules and Regulations
tkelley on DSK3SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
if viewed as a single financial
institution because of the mutual
support provisions for the FCS
institutions, has assets worth more than
$230 billion. According to the ICBA, the
FCS may be systemically important
under the Dodd-Frank Act because it
has assets in excess of $50 billion. The
ICBA also suggested that the
Commission should not provide any
exemptions for any institution with over
$50 billion in assets because institutions
over $50 billion are considered to be
potentially systemically important
under the Dodd-Frank Act.
In contrast, the FCC commented that
the FCS banks have strong protections
in place for counterparty default,
including, for example, collateral
posting agreements, which are overseen
by the FCA. According to the FCC, these
protections have been effective
throughout the recent financial crisis.
Accordingly, the FCC suggested that the
FCS poses no systemic risk to the U.S.
financial system.
The fact that Congress designated the
FCS as a GSE does not by itself imply
the existence of a sufficiently higher
level of risk to justify rejecting the
limited exemption from clearing
provided to cooperatives. The
Commission notes that the FCS is
supervised by the FCA, an independent
Federal agency charged with overseeing
the safety and soundness of the FCS.45
The Commission acknowledged in the
NPRM that the proposed exemption
would be available to cooperatives with
total assets in excess of $50 billion.
However, the Commission believes that
the exemption, as narrowly drafted, is
appropriate given the benefits conferred
by it to the entities Congress designated
for the end-user exception who are
members of exempt cooperatives.
Regarding the possible designation of
the FCS as systemically important, the
Commission notes that Congress
excluded the possibility of the FCS from
being designated as systemically
important by the Financial Stability
Oversight Council.46
The CFC requested that the
Commission, when coordinating with
45 See 12 U.S.C. 2241 (establishing the FCA); 12
U.S.C. 2252 (enumerating the powers of the FCA
including the power to ensure the safety and
soundness of FCS institutions).
46 The Financial Stability Oversight Council does
not have the authority to determine that the FCS be
supervised by the Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System as a ‘‘nonbank financial company’’
pursuant to section 113 of the Dodd-Frank Act. The
definition of ‘‘nonbank financial company’’
includes a ‘‘U.S. nonbank financial company’’ and
a ‘‘U.S. nonbank financial company’’ specifically
excludes a ‘‘Farm Credit System institution
chartered and subject to the provisions of the Farm
Credit Act of 1971.’’ 12 U.S.C. 5311(a)(4); section
102(a)(4)(B) of the Dodd-Frank Act.
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:26 Aug 21, 2013
Jkt 229001
the other prudential regulators working
to finalize the margin rules for noncleared swaps, ensure that the final
margin requirements for non-cleared
swaps are consistent with the final
cooperative exemption. In effect, the
CFC requested that the final margin
rules for non-cleared swaps not require
margin for swaps eligible for the
cooperative exemption.
The Commission intends to continue
to work with the other prudential
regulators to ensure that the cooperative
exemption, along with other clearing
exceptions or exemptions, are taken into
consideration when finalizing the
margin rules for non-cleared swaps.
The ICBA suggested that the
Commission should review the
exemption ‘‘every three years to see if
the exemption is warranted on an
ongoing basis’’ because cooperatives
will have had time to ‘‘adjust to the
evolving swaps markets and clearing
systems.’’
The Commission declines to include
an explicit sunset or study provision in
the final rule. As the Commission’s
swap regulations are new and the
market is evolving in response, the
Commission anticipates evaluating its
swap-related regulations on an asneeded basis and will modify them as
appropriate.
The ABA requested that the
Commission extend the comment period
for this rule because of the ‘‘impending
regulatory deadlines, complexity, and
economic consequences’’ of the
cooperative exemption.
The Commission declines to extend
the comment period because the public
was given an opportunity to, and did,
participate in the rulemaking process.
IV. Section 4(c) of the Commodity
Exchange Act
Section 4(c)(1) of the CEA states that
‘‘[i]n order to promote responsible
economic or financial innovation and
fair competition’’ the CFTC may exempt
any agreement, contract, or transaction
subject to section 4(a) from the
requirements of that section or any other
section of the CEA. Section 4(c)
authorizes the Commission to grant
exemptive relief to foster the
development or continuance of market
practices that contribute to market
innovation and competition.47 Congress,
in adding section 4(c) to the CEA,
intended that the Commission, ‘‘in
considering fair competition, will
implement this provision in a fair and
even-handed manner.’’ 48 At the same
time, Congress expected that, in doing
so, the Commission ‘‘will apply
consistent standards based on the
underlying facts and circumstances of
the transaction and markets being
considered, and may make distinctions
between exchanges and other markets
taking into account the particular facts
and circumstances involved, consistent
with the public interest and the
purposes of the Act, where such
distinctions are not arbitrary and
capricious.’’ 49 While this language
refers specifically to distinctions
between exchanges and other markets, it
implies that Congress more generally
expected the Commission, in applying
section 4(c)(1), to draw distinctions
among different market participants
where circumstances justify it.50 As
discussed in detail elsewhere herein,
cooperatives are unique in their
organizational form, in the way that
they act in the interests of their
members, and in the well-established
public policies that support the ability
of cooperative members to make use of
their cooperatives for purposes of
accessing markets. These unique
characteristics justify an exemption
specifically tailored to enable nonfinancial entity end users that are
members of cooperatives to realize the
full benefits of the end-user exception
when they access markets through their
cooperatives.
The end-user exception provided in
section 2(h)(7) of the CEA is not
available to an entity that is a ‘‘financial
entity,’’ as defined in section
2(h)(7)(C)(i), unless the entity is exempt
from the definition because it is a small
financial institution based on total
assets, as provided in section
2(h)(7)(C)(ii) of the CEA and § 50.50(d),
or it meets one of the narrowly drawn
exemptions provided in section 2(h)(7)
or the Commission regulations. Section
2(h)(7)(C)(ii) does not provide special
consideration for cooperatives that meet
the definition of ‘‘financial entity’’ and,
therefore, the asset size limit applies to
them.
As described in the NPRM and above,
cooperatives whose member-owners
consist exclusively of persons or entities
48 Id.
47 See
Conference Report, H.R. Report 102–978 at
8 (Oct. 2, 1992) (‘‘The goal of providing the
Commission with broad exemptive powers . . . is
to give the Commission a means of providing
certainty and stability to existing and emerging
markets so that financial innovation and market
development can proceed in an effective and
competitive manner.’’).
PO 00000
Frm 00011
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
52295
at 78.
49 Id.
50 Cf., CEA section 4(c)(2)(A), 7 U.S.C. 6(c)(2)(A)
(expressly requiring a determination that an
exemption from CEA section 4(a), 7 U.S.C. 6, under
CEA section 4(c)(1), 7 U.S.C. 6(c)(1), be consistent
with the public interest and the purposes of the
CEA, one of which is ‘‘to promote . . . fair
competition . . . among . . . market participants’’).
E:\FR\FM\22AUR2.SGM
22AUR2
tkelley on DSK3SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
52296
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 163 / Thursday, August 22, 2013 / Rules and Regulations
that could elect the end-user exception
provide important financial services to
their members. These cooperatives are,
in many respects, an extension of their
member-owners and are not separable
from their members in any real sense
because their mission is to act in the
interests of the members. However,
some of those cooperatives meet the
definition of ‘‘financial entity’’ and have
total assets in excess of $10 billion, and
therefore the end-user exception is
unavailable to them. By extension, the
full benefits of the end-user exemption
would be unavailable to their members
accessing financial services through
their cooperatives. Accordingly, absent
this exemption, cooperative members
would lose the ability to use their
cooperative for financial services and at
the same time, realize the full benefits
of end-user exception. Without the
cooperative exemption, when a
cooperative engages in financial activity
that could benefit from the end-user
exception and that activity is in the
interest of the cooperative’s members,
the members would not realize the full
benefits of the end-user exception
because the cooperative cannot elect the
exception. Although the members of a
cooperative may seek out financial
services from other market participants,
some of which may be able to elect the
end-user exception, such members
would not be able to realize the same
benefits as if they had acted through the
cooperative. As previously explained,
such other market participants were not
established solely to serve the interests
of its customers, and thus do not
provide the same benefits to its
customers as the cooperative structure
provides to its members, even for
similar services. Absent this exception,
the members of the cooperative would
no longer be able to fully realize the
benefits for which the cooperatives were
established of being the members’
intermediary in the financial markets
acting in the mutual interests of the
members. In light of this, the
Commission determined to exercise its
authority under section 4(c) of the CEA
to propose § 39.6(f) (now § 50.51) and
establish the cooperative exemption.
As noted above, section 4(c) of the
CEA authorizes the Commission to
provide exemptions to classes of
persons ‘‘to promote responsible
economic or financial innovation and
fair competition.’’ Many of the
comments focused on this provision.
For example, the ICBA commented that
the cooperative exemption does not
promote financial innovation.
According to the ICBA, the
Commission’s estimate that the
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:26 Aug 21, 2013
Jkt 229001
cooperative exemption would affect 500
or less swaps a year shows that there is
no financial innovation by the exempt
cooperatives. The ICBA also commented
that the Commission has not shown
financial innovation because the
proposal excludes the FHL Banks,
which, according to the ICBA would
potentially provide just as much, ‘‘if not
more,’’ financial innovation than an
exemption for the FCS and credit
unions. In essence, the ICBA stated that
the cooperative exemption does not
promote financial innovation because it
is narrowly tailored and affects only a
small number of swaps and institutions.
In contrast, the FCC commented that
‘‘[t]o provide tailored financing
products for farmers and farm-related
businesses, FCS institutions rely on the
safe use of derivatives to manage
interest rate, liquidity, and balance
sheet risk, primarily in the form of
interest rate swaps.’’
As discussed above in this section IV,
Congress contemplated that section 4(c)
of the CEA would provide the
Commission with the ‘‘means of
providing certainty and stability to
existing and emerging markets so that
financial innovation and market
development can proceed in an effective
and competitive manner.’’ 51 Financial
cooperatives have existed for over 100
years and were given separate legal
status by Congress as far back as 1916.52
Without these cooperatives, members
have less choice in where they can
borrow capital and hedge risks related
to those borrowing activities. Swaps are
a fairly recent innovation in the
financial markets that has become an
integral part of borrowing and lending.
The cooperative form has enabled
members to manage their borrowing
activities and to use swaps to hedge
risks in connection therewith at a lower
cost. By pooling member capital in
financial cooperatives, members are in
effect aggregating their resources to
allow them not only to gain a lower cost
of funding, but also to be able to hire
experienced executives who, as
employees of the cooperative, are
charged with managing the financial
activities of the cooperative and
advising the board of directors of the
cooperative for the benefit of the
member-owners, who often have
specific, shared purposes that are the
mission focus of the cooperative.53
51 See Conference Report, H.R. Report 102–978 at
8 (October 2, 1992).
52 See The Federal Farm Loan Act, Public Law
64–158, 39 Stat. 360 (1916) (repealed 1923) (a
predecessor to the Farm Credit Act).
53 See, e.g., the mission statement of the Farm
Credit Bank of Texas: ‘‘Other lenders may lend to
agriculture and rural America only when it is
PO 00000
Frm 00012
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
Further, because the cooperative
members elect the board members of the
cooperative on a democratic, one
member, one vote, basis,54 and often
most, if not all, board members are
cooperative members,55 the
membership, through the governing
board, has a unique opportunity to
better understand the benefits and risks
of swaps used in connection with their
financial activities and as a group
control the thoughtful application
thereof in a responsible manner and for
their mutual benefit. The mutual benefit
of pooling resources and acting
cooperatively is one of the principal
policy reasons for the establishment of
cooperative structures.56 These are
benefits that the cooperative memberowners would not have as customers of
other financial institutions that they do
not own or control and that are not
established with the mission of
providing financing and financial
services to a particular type of customer
and for their benefit.
In addition, section 4(c) of the CEA
does not specify that the financial
profitable to do so, but at Farm Credit, financing
rural America is all we do. When Congress created
the Farm Credit System in 1916, it gave the System
a mission to be a competitive, reliable source of
funds for eligible borrowers in agriculture and rural
America. Because we specialize in these areas, we
have expertise that is unparalleled among other
lenders.’’ https://www.farmcreditbank.com/farmcredit-advantage.aspx; See also CoBank 2011
Annual Report, 31 (‘‘We are a mission-based lender
with authority to make loans and provide related
financial services to eligible borrowers in the
agribusiness and rural utility industries, and to
certain related entities, as defined by the Farm
Credit Act. . . . We are cooperatively owned by our
U.S. customers.’’).
54 To receive treatment as cooperatives under the
Internal Revenue Code, an entity must be
‘‘operating on a cooperative basis.’’ 26 U.S.C.
1381(a). The United States Tax Court has held that
one of the guiding principles for determining
whether an entity is operating on a cooperative
basis is if it is democratically controlled by the
members. Puget Sound Plywood, Inc. v.
Commissioner, 44 T.C. 305, 308 (1965).
55 See, e.g., 12 U.S.C. 2072, 92 (requiring boards
for production credit associations and federal land
bank associations be selected from its voting
members); 12 CFR 701 app. A (bylaws for national
credit unions requiring board members be members
of the credit union); Kan. Stat. Ann. § 17–1510
(West) (requiring board members to be selected
from the membership); Va. Code Ann. § 13.1–324
(West) (requiring the board, except for the public
director, consist of members).
56 See, e.g., the initial statement of Congress in the
Farm Credit System Act, which authorizes the Farm
Credit System that the FCS cooperatives are a part
of: ‘‘It is the objective of this chapter to continue
to encourage farmer- and rancher-borrowers
participation in the management, control, and
ownership of a permanent system of credit for
agriculture which will be responsive to the credit
needs of all types of agricultural producers having
a basis for credit, and to modernize and improve the
authorizations and means for furnishing such credit
and credit for housing in rural areas made available
through the institutions constituting the Farm
Credit System as herein provided.’’ 12 U.S.C. 2001.
E:\FR\FM\22AUR2.SGM
22AUR2
tkelley on DSK3SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 163 / Thursday, August 22, 2013 / Rules and Regulations
innovation realized must be of a certain
size. Innovation often begins on a small
scale before becoming widely accepted
and implemented, if successful.
Regarding whether the FHL Banks
should be included because the
exemption would also provide
innovation through the FHL Banks, as
described in detail above in section III.B
of this final release, the Commission
determined to carefully narrow the
cooperatives that can elect the
exemption to those whose members
consist exclusively of entities that (or
other cooperatives whose members) do
qualify for the end-user exception on
their own, given the clear Congressional
intent in section 2(h)(7) of the CEA to
exclude financial entities (the definition
of which excludes small financial
institutions) from the end-user
exception to the clearing requirement.
Given that FHL Banks are not made up
exclusively of non-financial entities or
small financial institutions, the
cooperative exemption would not be
available to them.
The ABA and ICBA also commented
that the cooperative exemption does not
qualify under section 4(c) and is
discriminatory because it would give
cooperatives a competitive advantage
over banks and therefore it does not
promote ‘‘fair competition.’’ They also
commented that cooperatives compete
with banks for the same business
opportunities, and as GSEs and taxexempt entities, cooperatives can offer
more competitive pricing than
traditional banks. Lake City Bank
commented that it has difficulty
competing with the FCS and credit
unions for business due to the GSE
status of the FCS, the large amount of
assets the FCS maintains, and the
favorable tax status afforded to the FCS
and credit unions.
In contrast, the FCC commented that
the cooperative exemption preserves a
‘‘level field for FCS institutions and
commercial banks’’ that qualify for the
end-user exception because FCS
associations that otherwise would
qualify as small financial institutions
and compete with qualifying banks
hedge risk at the level of the FCS bank
cooperatives in which they are
members. In effect, the FCC asserts that
the FCS associations would be unable to
use the end-user exception because the
cooperative structure of the FCS system
means that the associations act through
the FCS bank cooperatives (all of which
have total assets over $10 billion) for
their hedging activities and not directly.
As discussed previously, the essential
function of cooperatives is to enable
their members to access markets
through a commonly-owned
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:26 Aug 21, 2013
Jkt 229001
intermediary. The memberships of the
cooperatives that would qualify for the
cooperative exemption consist of
entities that can elect the end-user
exception if acting on their own or other
cooperatives the members of which can
elect the end-user exception. However,
these cooperatives meet the definition of
‘‘financial entity’’ and are too large to
qualify for the small financial
institution exemption, which, in turn,
renders the end-user exception
unavailable to the cooperatives.
Accordingly, if the cooperative members
wish to access the markets through their
financial cooperative, which has been
established for that same purpose, they
would not receive the full benefits of the
end-user exception because the
cooperative would have to clear its
swaps even though it is acting in the
interests of its members in the markets.
On the other hand, the members could
enter into loans and swaps with other
financial entities that can elect the enduser exception. In effect, the cooperative
structure, which is intended to give the
members the benefit of size by allowing
them to pool their resources and act
together for their mutual benefit, instead
would frustrate their ability to realize
the full benefits of the end-user
exception when acting through their
cooperatives. As such, the cooperative
exemption seeks to preserve the benefits
available to the members of cooperatives
as intended under the cooperative legal
structure.
The Commission’s recognition that
the cooperatives provide a means for its
members to access the financial markets
in a variety of ways is consistent with
the intent of Congress and state
legislatures in the laws establishing
cooperative legal structures. As
described below, some of these laws
acknowledge that cooperatives may
have certain benefits or advantages that
other entities do not have, but that any
such advantages are acceptable for
promoting the benefits of cooperatives
because ultimately the benefits inure to
the members of the cooperatives. The
cooperative exemption is being adopted
by the Commission in the context of the
foregoing policy determinations.57
57 As an example of these legislative policy
determinations, the Federal Credit Union Act states:
The Congress finds the following:
(1) The American credit union movement began
as a cooperative effort to serve the productive and
provident credit needs of individuals of modest
means.
(2) Credit unions continue to fulfill this public
purpose, and current members and membership
groups should not face divestiture from the
financial services institution of their choice as a
result of recent court action.
(3) To promote thrift and credit extension, a
meaningful affinity and bond among members,
PO 00000
Frm 00013
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
52297
Importantly, the Commission notes
that the swaps that are the subject of the
exemption are limited to those swaps
related to member loans. Accordingly,
the exemption applies only to the swaps
related to lending services that financial
cooperatives have been established to
provide, and traditionally do provide, to
their owner-members.58
The ABA and ICBA also cited to
‘‘preferred tax and funding advantages
as [GSEs]’’ for FCS banks and the taxexempt status that qualifying
cooperatives have under Subchapter T
of the Federal Internal Revenue Code
(‘‘Tax Code’’) as existing advantages
cooperatives have over banks. On the
other hand, financial cooperatives, such
as the FCS and credit unions, are subject
to other legal restrictions and regulated
by their own regulators, who may
impose restrictions that put them at a
competitive disadvantage when
compared to banks. For example, federal
statutes and regulations applicable to
FCS cooperatives restrict lending
services to particular classes of
borrowers, prohibit them from taking
deposits (which limits their funding
sources as compared to banks), and
manifested by a commonality of routine interaction,
shared and related work experiences, interests, or
activities, or the maintenance of an otherwise well
understood sense of cohesion or identity is essential
to the fulfillment of the public mission of credit
unions.
(4) Credit unions, unlike many other participants
in the financial services market, are exempt from
Federal and most State taxes because they are
member-owned, democratically operated, not-forprofit organizations generally managed by volunteer
boards of directors and because they have the
specified mission of meeting the credit and savings
needs of consumers, especially persons of modest
means.
(5) Improved credit union safety and soundness
provisions will enhance the public benefit that
citizens receive from these cooperative financial
services institutions.
12 U.S.C. 1751. State cooperative laws also
acknowledge the different status cooperatives are
being provided within the competitive landscape.
See N.Y. Coop. Corp. Law, which states that: ‘‘[a]
cooperative corporation shall be classed as a nonprofit corporation, since its primary object is not to
make profits for itself as such, or to pay dividends
on invested capital, but to provide service and
means whereby its members may have the
economic advantage of cooperative action,
including a reasonable and fair return for their
product and service.’’ N.Y. Coop. Corp. Law 3
(McKinney) (emphasis added); see also Ky. Rev.
Stat. Ann. § 272.1001(2) (West 2012).
58 For example, with respect to the FCS, the Farm
Credit Act of 1971 provides, ‘‘It is declared to be
the policy of the Congress, recognizing that a
prosperous, productive agriculture is essential to a
free nation and recognizing the growing need for
credit in rural areas, that the farmer-owned
cooperative Farm Credit System be designed to
accomplish the objective of improving the income
and well-being of American farmers and ranchers
by furnishing sound, adequate, and constructive
credit and closely related services to them, their
cooperatives, and to selected farm-related
businesses necessary for efficient farm operations.’’
12 U.S.C. 2001.
E:\FR\FM\22AUR2.SGM
22AUR2
tkelley on DSK3SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
52298
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 163 / Thursday, August 22, 2013 / Rules and Regulations
limit other services that they can
provide to members. Similarly, the Tax
Code, U.S. Tax Court rulings, and other
guidance from the Internal Revenue
Service impose limits on the business
structure of cooperatives that seek
cooperative tax treatment under the Tax
Code that may impact their
competitiveness. Also, cooperatives
generally cannot raise equity capital
from independent, non-customer
investors. While the Commission’s role
is not to determine the relative overall
competitive advantages or
disadvantages that cooperatives or other
financial institutions may have, the
Commission believes that any limited
advantage the cooperative exemption
may provide to exempt cooperatives is
likely to be small when viewed in the
context of the complete competitive
landscape in which financial
cooperatives and banks operate.
Given that § 39.6(f) (now § 50.51) and
its attendant terms and conditions
would (1) promote economic and
financial innovation for the benefit of
the members of exempt cooperatives, (2)
foster the ability of cooperative
members to access the financial markets
through their cooperatives and (3)
further Congressional intent by
providing a limited exemption from
clearing that effectively extends the enduser exception to cooperatives that have
end users for members, the Commission
concludes that the adoption of § 39.6(f)
(now § 50.51) and its attendant terms
and conditions would promote
responsible economic and financial
innovation and fair competition in
accordance with section 4(c) of the CEA.
The Commission also concludes that
the cooperative exemption will be
limited to entities that fall within the
term ‘‘appropriate person,’’ as required
by section 4(c)(2)(B)(i) of the CEA.59
Section 2(e) of the CEA renders it
‘‘unlawful for any person, other than an
[eligible contract participant (‘‘ECP’’)],
to enter into a swap unless the swap is
entered into on, or subject to the rules
of, a board of trade designated as a
contract market.’’ 60 Since the
cooperative exemption can only be
elected for swaps that are executed
bilaterally and not on a board of trade
or contract market, both the exempt
cooperatives and their respective
counterparties to such swaps must be
ECPs. Given that the criteria for the ECP
definition covering business
organizations generally is more
restrictive than the comparable criteria
for the appropriate person definition in
59 7
U.S.C. 6(c)(2)(B)(i).
60 7 U.S.C. 2(e).
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:26 Aug 21, 2013
Jkt 229001
section 4(c)(3),61 the Commission finds
that the class of persons relying on
§ 50.51(a) will be limited to appropriate
persons for purposes of CEA section
4(c)(2)(B)(i).62
Furthermore, the Commission
concludes that the cooperative
exemption will not have a material
adverse effect on the ability of the
Commission or any contract market or
derivatives transaction execution
facility to discharge their respective
regulatory duties under the CEA as
provided in section 4(c)(2)(B)(ii) of the
CEA. The cooperative exemption
effectively extends the end-user
exception established in section 2(h)(7)
of the CEA to cooperatives acting for
non-financial entities. Section 39.6(f)(3)
(now § 50.51(c)) has the same reporting
requirement that the end-user exception
has with the only difference being that
the reporting party must report that the
cooperative exemption has been elected
for the swap being reported instead of
the end-user exception. In this way, the
Commission will be able to track the
swaps for which the cooperative
exemption is being elected and who is
electing the exemption thereby allowing
the Commission to oversee the use of
the cooperative exemption in the same
manner as the end-user exception.
Regarding contract markets and
derivatives transaction execution
facilities, the cooperative exemption
does not modify their regulatory duties
under the CEA. Accordingly, those
entities will not have any increase or
reduction in their regulatory duties with
regard to the exempted swaps.
V. Administrative Procedure Act
Related Comments
The ABA and the ICBA submitted a
number of comments asserting that the
rule is discriminatory or violates the
61 Compare CEA section 4(c)(3)(F) identifying the
applicable type of appropriate person (a
‘‘corporation, partnership, proprietorship,
organization, trust, or other business entity with a
net worth exceeding $1,000,000 or total assets
exceeding $5,000,000 . . .’’ and section 1a(18)(A)(v)
that identifies a comparable type of ECP (a
‘‘corporation, partnership, proprietorship,
organization, trust, or other entity’’ with a net worth
exceeding $1,000,000 (and that enters into an
agreement, contract or transaction for certain risk
management purposes) or total assets exceeding
$10,000,000).
62 Although § 39.6(f) (now § 50.51) is an
exemption from the clearing requirement of section
2(h)(1)(A) of the CEA and section 2(e) of the CEA
sets forth a standard for entering into a swap,
section 4(c)(2)(B)(i) requires that any agreement,
contract or transaction that is the subject of a CEA
section 4(c)(1) exemption be ‘‘entered into’’ solely
between appropriate persons. Therefore, focusing
on section 2(e), which is an execution standard
rather than a clearing standard, is appropriate,
particularly given that if it is unlawful to enter into
a swap in the first instance, the clearing
requirement is moot.
PO 00000
Frm 00014
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
arbitrary and capricious standard in the
APA.63 The ABA commented that the
Commission did not provide a
reasonable explanation for why
cooperatives with over $10 billion in
total assets were given an exemption
while banks with total assets over $10
billion were not. According to the ABA,
the Commission did not take into
account the Congressional intent not to
exempt banks and cooperatives with
total assets above $10 billion from
mandatory clearing.
The Commission disagrees with the
commenters’ assertion that the
Commission did not provide a
reasonable explanation for the rule or
that it does not fulfill Congressional
intent. As discussed throughout the
NPRM and as reiterated in this final
release in response to specific
comments, the cooperative exemption
fulfills Congressional intent as
expressed in section 2(h)(7) of the CEA
by providing the full benefits of the enduser exception to the end-user members
of cooperatives who act in the markets
through their cooperatives. The
limitation on the definition of ‘‘exempt
cooperative’’ to those cooperatives
whose members consist exclusively of
entities and persons who may elect the
end-user exception and other
cooperatives whose members meet that
requirement makes that readily apparent
and is explained in detail in the
NPRM.64 Furthermore, the Commission
considered both this element of
Congressional intent and Congress’ clear
mandate that the Commission require
that certain swaps entered into by
financial institutions be cleared by
carefully and purposefully limiting the
types of swaps for which the
cooperative exemption is available.65
The Commission’s reasoning behind the
cooperative exemption based on the
unique member-owner structure of
cooperatives and the nature of
cooperatives as entities whose primary
purpose is to act in the interests of their
member-owners in the financial
marketplace is thoroughly discussed
throughout the NPRM and reiterated in
this final release. Commenters’
assertions that the cooperative
exemption rule is inconsistent with
Congressional intent or is arbitrary and
capricious are therefore without merit.
63 See
64 77
5 U.S.C. 706(2)(A).
FR 41942 and 41943, and section III.B
above.
65 77 FR 41942 and 41943, and section III.C
above.
E:\FR\FM\22AUR2.SGM
22AUR2
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 163 / Thursday, August 22, 2013 / Rules and Regulations
VI. Consideration of Costs and Benefits
A. Background
In the wake of the financial crisis of
2008, Congress adopted the Dodd-Frank
Act, which, among other things,
requires the Commission to determine
whether a particular swap, or group,
category, type or class of swaps, shall be
required to be cleared.66 Specifically,
section 723(a)(3) of the Dodd-Frank Act
amended section 2(h)(1)(A) of the CEA
to make it ‘‘unlawful for any person to
engage in a swap unless that person
submits such swap for clearing to a
[DCO] that is registered under the CEA
or a [DCO] that is exempt from
registration under [the CEA] if the swap
is required to be cleared.’’ This clearing
requirement is designed to reduce
counterparty risk associated with swaps
and, in turn, mitigate the potential
systemic impact of such risk and reduce
the likelihood for swaps to cause or
exacerbate instability in the financial
system.67
Notwithstanding the benefits of
clearing, section 2(h)(7) of the CEA
provides the end-user exception if one
of the swap counterparties: ‘‘(i) is not a
financial entity; (ii) is using swaps to
hedge or mitigate commercial risk; and
(iii) notifies the Commission, in a
manner set forth by the Commission,
how it generally meets its financial
obligations associated with entering into
non-cleared swaps.’’ Section
2(h)(7)(C)(ii) of the CEA directs the
Commission to consider making the
end-user exception available to small
banks, savings associations, credit
unions, and farm credit institutions,
including those institutions with total
assets of $10 billion or less, through an
exemption from the definition of
66 See
section 2(h)(2) of the CEA, 7 U.S.C. 2(h)(2).
a bilateral swap is moved into clearing,
the DCO becomes the counterparty to each of the
original participants in the swap. This standardizes
counterparty risk for the original swap participants
in that they each bear the same risk attributable to
facing the DCO as counterparty. In addition, DCOs
exist for the primary purpose of managing credit
exposure from the swaps being cleared and
therefore DCOs are effective at mitigating
counterparty risk through the use of risk
management frameworks. These frameworks model
risk and collect defined levels of initial and
variation margin from the counterparties that are
adjusted for changing market conditions and use
guarantee funds and other risk management tools
for the purpose of assuring that, in the event of a
member default, all other counterparties remain
whole. DCOs have demonstrated resilience in the
face of past market stress. Most recently, they
remained financially sound and effectively settled
positions in the midst of turbulent events in 2007–
2008 that threatened the financial health and
stability of many other types of entities and the
financial system as a whole. These, and other
benefits of clearing, are explained more fully at: 77
FR 74284.
tkelley on DSK3SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
67 When
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:26 Aug 21, 2013
Jkt 229001
‘‘financial entity.’’ 68 In § 39.6(d) (now
§ 50.50(d)), the Commission established
the small financial institution
exemption from the definition of
‘‘financial entity’’ for these institutions.
The small financial institution
exemption largely adopted the language
of section 2(h)(7)(C)(ii) providing for an
exemption for the institutions identified
in section 2(h)(7)(C)(ii) that have total
assets of $10 billion or less.
On December 23, 2010, the
Commission published for public
comment an NPRM for § 39.6 (now
§ 50.50) proposing the end-user
exception.69 As discussed in section I
hereof, several parties that commented
on the end-user exception NPRM
recommended that the Commission
provide extend the end-user exception
to cooperatives. These commenters
reasoned 70 that the member ownership
structure of cooperatives and the fact
that they act in the interests of members
that are non-financial entities justified
an extension of the end-user exception
to the cooperatives. In effect, the
commenters posited that because a
cooperative effectively acts as an
intermediary for its members when
facing the larger financial markets with
its interests being effectively the same as
its members’ interests, the end-user
exception that would be available to a
cooperative’s members should also be
available to the cooperative. If the
members themselves could elect the
end-user exception, then, according to
the commenters, the Commission
should permit the cooperatives to do so
as well.
The Commission is adopting the
cooperative exemption herein as
described in this release. Through
§ 39.6(f) (now § 50.51), the Commission
uses the authority provided in section
4(c) of the CEA to permit ‘‘exempt
cooperatives,’’ as defined in § 39.6(f)(1)
(now § 50.51(a)) to elect not to clear
certain swaps that are otherwise
required to be cleared pursuant to
section 2(h)(1)(A) of the CEA. In effect,
the cooperative exemption makes
available to exempt cooperatives the
end-user exception that is available to
their members, as described in greater
detail above.71 It is the costs and
68 See
section 2(h)(7)(C)(ii) of the CEA.
75 FR 80747.
70 Other reasons given for providing an
exemption from clearing for cooperatives are
discussed above in this final rule.
71 Exempt cooperatives can be financial entities
that do not qualify for the small financial institution
exemption because their assets exceed $10 billion.
As provided in § 39.6(f)(2) (now § 50.51(b)) of the
rule, an exempt cooperative would not be required
to clear swaps with members in connection with
originating member loans, or swaps used by the
exempt cooperative to hedge or mitigate
69 See
PO 00000
Frm 00015
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
52299
benefits of this exemption that the
Commission considered in the
discussion that follows.
B. Statutory Requirement To Consider
the Costs and Benefits of the
Commission’s Action: CEA Section 15(a)
Section 15(a) of the CEA requires the
Commission to consider the costs and
benefits of its actions before
promulgating a regulation under the
CEA or issuing certain orders. Section
15(a) further specifies that the costs and
benefits shall be evaluated in light of the
following five broad areas of market and
public concern: (1) Protection of market
participants and the public; (2)
efficiency, competitiveness and
financial integrity of futures markets; (3)
price discovery; (4) sound risk
management practices; and (5) other
public interest considerations.
Accordingly, the Commission considers
the costs and benefits resulting from its
own discretionary determinations with
respect to the section 15(a) factors.
Absent this rulemaking, all
cooperatives that are financial entities
as defined in section 2(h)(7)(C)(i) of the
CEA and which are not otherwise
exempt from that definition would be
subject to the clearing requirement
under section 2(h)(7)(A)(i) of the CEA.
Thus, the scenario against which this
rulemaking’s costs and benefits are
considered is cooperatives within the
definition of financial entity in Section
2(h)(7)(C)(i) with assets exceeding $10
billion, which remain subject to the
clearing requirement of section
2(h)(1)(A) of the CEA. Additionally, the
Commission considers the rulemaking’s
costs and benefits relative to alternatives
considered by the Commission.
As discussed in more detail below,
the Commission is able to estimate
certain reporting costs. The dollar
estimates are offered as ranges with
upper and lower bounds, which is
necessary to accommodate the
uncertainty that surrounds them. The
discussion below considers the rule’s
costs and benefits as well as alternatives
to the rule. The discussion concludes
with a consideration of the rule’s costs
and benefits in light of the five factors
specified in section 15(a) of the CEA.
C. Costs and Benefits of the Final Rule
1. Costs and Benefits to Electing
Cooperatives and Their Members
Providing an exemption from required
clearing to cooperatives that meet the
criteria described in the final rule will
benefit them and their members in that
they will not have to bear the costs of
commercial risk arising in connection with such
swaps with members or loans to members.
E:\FR\FM\22AUR2.SGM
22AUR2
52300
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 163 / Thursday, August 22, 2013 / Rules and Regulations
tkelley on DSK3SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
clearing that they would otherwise
incur. Without the cooperative
exemption rule, cooperatives meeting
the criteria of the exemption would
have to clear swaps pursuant to section
2(h)(1)(A) of the CEA when they are
either: (1) Entering into a swap with a
member that is subject to required
clearing, or (2) transacting with another
financial entity to hedge or mitigate risk
related to loans with members or swaps
with members related to such loans.
Required clearing would introduce
additional costs for cooperatives,
including fees associated with clearing
as well as costs associated with margin
and capital requirements.
Regarding fees, DCOs typically charge
Futures Commission Merchants
(‘‘FCMs’’) an initial transaction fee for
each of the FCM customers’ swaps that
are cleared, as well as an annual
maintenance fee for each of their
customers’ open positions.72 As a result,
cooperatives eligible for the exemption
will bear lower costs related to swaps
and would likely pass along these costs
savings to their members either by
providing swaps at more attractive rates
or through larger patronage distributions
or allocations.73
The ABA questioned whether the
exemption would have benefits that
accrue to members of exempt
cooperatives. The ABA stated that in the
absence of the proposed exemption,
cooperative members can still exempt
their swaps from clearing. Therefore, the
ABA believes that ‘‘the proposed
clearing exemption would solely benefit
cooperatives larger than $10 billion.’’
The Commission, however,
anticipates that benefits will accrue to
members of exempt cooperatives.
Generally, as discussed in section IV,
the mission of the cooperatives is to
provide loans and other financial
services to particular types of borrowers
and the cooperatives operate for the
mutual benefit of their respective
members. As such, in keeping with its
mission and purpose, a cooperative is
likely to elect the exemption only if the
election thereof benefits its members. As
72 For example, not including customer-specific
and volume discounts, the transaction fees for
interest rate swaps at CME range from $1 to $24 per
million notional amount and the maintenance fees
are $2 per year per million notional amount for
open positions. LCH transaction fees for interest
rate swaps range from $1 to $20 per million
notional amount, and the maintenance fee ranges
from $5 to $20 per swap per month, depending on
the number of outstanding swap positions that an
entity has with the DCO. See LCH pricing for
clearing services related to OTC interest rate swaps
at: https://www.lchclearnet.com/swaps/swapclear_
for_clearing_members/fees.asp.
73 The CUNA stated that the exemption ‘‘would
help minimize the additional costs and fees
associated with mandatory clearing.’’
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:26 Aug 21, 2013
Jkt 229001
discussed further in this section VI, the
exemption is likely to lower operational
costs for exempt cooperatives and to
reduce their margin requirements. As a
consequence, exempt cooperatives will
be able to provide lower-cost funding to
their members, to retain more member
allocable capital, or to pay out higher
patronage distributions to their
members. Ultimately, the members, as
owners of the cooperatives, will benefit.
Regarding margin requirements, by
allowing cooperatives to exempt certain
swaps from clearing, the final rule may
reduce the amount of margin that
exempt cooperatives and their
counterparties are required to post for
swaps used to hedge or mitigate risk
associated with loans to eligible
members and for swaps related to those
loans.74 Reduced margin requirements
will reduce the amount of capital that
exempt cooperatives must allocate to
margin, which will increase the amount
of capital that exempt cooperatives may
distribute or allocate to members. On
the other hand, to the extent that the
exemption results in exempt
cooperatives and their counterparties
holding less margin against exempt
swap positions, each will be exposed to
greater counterparty risk.
The final rule may also affect the
capital that cooperatives that are
financial entities are required to hold
with respect to their swap positions
pursuant to prudential regulatory
capital requirements. As stated above,
when compared to a situation in which
the cooperative exemption is not
available, the cooperative exemption
will reduce the number of swaps that
exempt cooperatives are required to
clear. The Commission anticipates that
reducing the number of swaps that such
cooperatives clear may impact the
amount of capital that exempt
cooperatives are required to hold. This
creates both benefits and costs. If
reduced clearing lowers the amount of
capital that exempt cooperatives must
hold, that would increase the
cooperative’s lending capacity, enabling
them to lend more to their members
without retaining or raising additional
capital. As for costs, this allows exempt
cooperatives to become more highly
leveraged, which increases the
counterparty risk that they pose to their
members and other market participants
with whom they transact. On the other
hand, if reduced clearing increases the
74 The Commission notes that regulations
addressing margin and capital requirements for
non-cleared swaps have not yet been finalized.
Accordingly, the Commission cannot determine,
quantify, or estimate what margin, if any, may be
required for the swaps exempted from clearing
under the cooperative exemption.
PO 00000
Frm 00016
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
amount of capital that exempt
cooperatives must hold, that would
have the opposite effect.
Cooperatives that elect the exemption
will be required to report, or to cause to
be reported, additional information to
an SDR or to the Commission, which
will create incremental costs for the
reporting party. The final rule requires
that exempt cooperatives adhere to the
reporting requirements of § 50.50(b). For
each swap where the exemption is
elected, either the exempt cooperative
or its counterparty (likely if the
counterparty is an SD or MSP) must
report: (1) That the election of the
exemption is being made; (2) which
party is the electing counterparty; and
(3) certain information specific to the
electing counterparty unless that
information has already been provided
by the electing counterparty through an
annual filing.75 In addition, for entities
that are registered with the SEC, the
reporting party will also be required to
report with respect to the electing
counterparty: (1) The SEC filer’s central
index key number; and (2) that an
appropriate committee of the board of
directors has approved the decision for
that entity to enter into swaps that are
exempt from the requirements of
sections 2(h)(1) and 2(h)(8) of the Act.
For each exempted swap, to comply
with the swap-by-swap reporting
requirements in §§ 50.50(b)(1)(i) and (ii),
the reporting counterparty will be
required to check one box indicating the
exemption is being elected and
complete one field identifying the
electing counterparty. The Commission
expects that this information will be
entered into the appropriate reporting
system concurrently with additional
information that is required by the CEA
and part 45 of the Commission’s
regulations. Furthermore, the
Commission estimates that there will be
approximately 500 swaps per year that
are exempted from clearing pursuant to
this rule.76 Therefore, each reporting
75 The third set of information comprises data that
is likely to remain relatively constant and therefore,
does not require swap-by-swap reporting and can be
reported less frequently.
76 A review of information provided for five
cooperatives that likely would be exempt
cooperatives showed a range of swap usage from
none to as many as approximately 200 swaps a year
with most entering into less than 50 swaps a year.
Using the high end of reported swaps for the five
cooperatives for which information was available,
an estimate of 50 swaps per year was calculated.
The Commission believes this estimate is high
because some of the reported swaps may not meet
the requirements of the final rule and, based on
discussions with other regulators, several
cooperatives for which detailed information was
not available to the Commission likely undertake
little, if any, swap activity. However, for purposes
of the cost calculations, the Commission assumes
E:\FR\FM\22AUR2.SGM
22AUR2
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 163 / Thursday, August 22, 2013 / Rules and Regulations
tkelley on DSK3SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
counterparty is likely to spend 15
seconds to 2 minutes per transaction in
incremental time entering the swap-byswap information into the reporting
system, or in the aggregate, 1.5 hours to
17 hours per year for all 500 estimated
swaps. A financial analyst’s average
salary is $208/hour, which corresponds
to approximately $1–$7 per transaction
or in aggregate, $300–$3,500 per year for
all 500 estimated swaps.77 While the
above information must be reported on
a swap-by-swap basis, some information
may be reported annually. Regulation
§ 50.50(b)(1)(iii) allows for certain
counterparty specific information
identified therein to be reported either
swap-by-swap by the reporting
counterparty or annually by the electing
counterparty. When exempt
cooperatives enter into exempt swaps
with members, the cooperative is likely
to be the reporting counterparty.
Furthermore, assuming the cooperative
is the reporting counterparty, the time
burden for the first swap entered into by
an exempt cooperative in collecting and
reporting the information required by
§ 50.50(b)(1)(iii) will be approximately
the same as the time burden for
collecting and reporting the information
for the annual filing. Given the cost
equivalence for annual reporting to
reporting a single swap if the exempt
cooperative is both the electing and
reporting counterparty, the Commission
assumes that all ten exempt
cooperatives will make an annual filing
of the information required for
§ 50.50(b)(1)(iii). The Commission
estimates that it will take an average of
30 minutes to 90 minutes to complete
and submit the annual filing. The
average hourly wage for a compliance
attorney is $300, which means that the
annual per cooperative cost for the filing
is likely to be between $150 and $450.
If all ten exempt cooperatives were to
undertake an annual filing, the aggregate
cost would be $1,500 to $4,500.78
that each of the 10 potential exempt cooperatives
will enter into 50 swaps each year. Accordingly, it
is estimated that exempt cooperatives may elect the
cooperative exemption for 500 swaps each year.
77 Wage estimates are taken from the SIFMA
‘‘Report on Management and Professional Earnings
in the Securities Industry 2011.’’ Hourly wages are
calculated assuming 1,800 hours per year and a
multiplier of 5.35 to account for overhead and
bonuses. In light of the challenges of developing
precise estimates, the results of calculations have
been rounded.
78 The average wage for a compliance attorney is
$300.95 [($112,505 per year)/(2,000 hours per year)
* 5.35 = $300.95]. For the purposes of the Cost
Benefit Considerations section, the Commission has
used wage estimates that are taken from the SIFMA
‘‘Report on Management and Professional Earnings
in the Securities Industry 2011’’ because industry
participants are likely to be more familiar with
them. Hourly costs are calculated assuming 2,000
hours per year and a multiplier of 5.35 to account
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:26 Aug 21, 2013
Jkt 229001
Furthermore, when an exempt
cooperative is not functioning as the
reporting counterparty (i.e., when
transacting with a SD or MSP), it may,
at certain times, need to communicate
information to its reporting
counterparties in order to facilitate
reporting. That information may
include, among other things, whether
the electing counterparty has filed an
annual report pursuant to § 50.50(b) and
information to facilitate any due
diligence that the reporting counterparty
may conduct. These costs will likely
vary substantially depending on the
number of different reporting
counterparties with whom an electing
counterparty conducts transactions,
how frequently the electing
counterparty enters into swaps, whether
the electing counterparty undertakes an
annual filing, and the due diligence that
the reporting counterparty chooses to
conduct. The Commission estimates that
non-reporting electing counterparties
will incur between 5 minutes and 10
hours of annual burden hours, or in the
aggregate, between approximately 1
hour and 100 hours. The hourly wage
for a compliance attorney is $300,
which means that the annual aggregate
cost for communicating information to
the reporting counterparty is likely to be
between $300 and $30,000. Given the
unknowns associated with this cost
estimate noted above, the Commission
does not believe this wide range can be
narrowed without further information.79
The ABA and the ICBA suggested that
the Commission’s assumption that each
potentially exempt cooperative engages
in 50 swaps a year does not take into
account the fact that the number of
swaps entered into by the exempt
cooperatives may change or increase
over time. The ABA also commented
that the Commission underestimated the
number of cooperatives eligible and
assumes that the number of cooperatives
would not increase by either
reorganization or growth.
The Commission contacted the FCA
and National Credit Union
Administration for further assistance in
assessing whether the estimates used in
the NPRM are reasonable. These
regulators discussed generally the
observed level of swap activity of the
cooperatives they regulate. Based on
these discussions, the Commission
concluded that the estimates in the
NPRM are reasonable and appropriate
for this rulemaking. The Commission
for overhead and bonuses. All totals calculated on
the basis of cost estimates are rounded to two
significant digits.
79 As noted above, the average wage for a
compliance attorney is $300.95 per hour [($112,505
per year)/(2,000 hours per year) * 5.35 = $300.95].
PO 00000
Frm 00017
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
52301
recognizes that the number of entities
eligible for the exemption and the
number of swaps per eligible
cooperative is likely to change in the
future and that the benefits of this
exemption for exempt cooperatives
could encourage the number or size of
exempt cooperatives and of swaps used
by those cooperatives to grow. However,
the Commission notes that the extent to
which such growth is realized also
depends on several additional factors
that the Commission does not have
adequate information to evaluate,
including: (1) Subsequent changes to
laws or regulations affecting one or
more types of cooperatives; (2) increases
or decreases in the size of the industries
served by those cooperatives; and (3) the
frequency with which exempt
cooperatives make loans or experience
other changes that require rebalancing
of their hedging strategies. Because the
Commission does not have sufficient
information to estimate the direction or
magnitude of the effect that these forces
will have on the number of exempt
cooperatives and exempt swaps per
cooperative, it is not possible to
evaluate how future changes in either
are likely to affect the costs or benefits
related to the exemption.
2. Costs and Benefits for Counterparties
to Electing Cooperatives
The benefits of the exemption for
counterparties to electing exempt
cooperatives differ depending on
whether they are members of the
cooperatives. For entities that are
members of the electing cooperative,
they will likely benefit from the reduced
operational costs the exempt
cooperative achieves through reduced
clearing fees associated with the
cooperative’s swaps with the market.
The benefit may be passed on in the
form of better terms on swaps between
members and the cooperative and
through the cooperative’s patronage
distributions to members. For entities
that are not members of the cooperative
(i.e. market makers entering into swaps
with the cooperative), the benefits are
different. Market makers entering into
swaps with cooperatives that are subject
to the exemption do not participate in
the pro rata patronage distributions, but
may benefit from reduced clearing costs
associated with non-cleared swaps.
Reduced clearing of swaps by exempt
cooperatives will increase counterparty
risk for both exempt cooperatives and
their counterparties. Cooperatives will
be more exposed to the credit risk of
their counterparties, and conversely, the
cooperatives’ counterparties will be
more exposed to the credit risk of the
exempt cooperatives. This could be
E:\FR\FM\22AUR2.SGM
22AUR2
52302
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 163 / Thursday, August 22, 2013 / Rules and Regulations
tkelley on DSK3SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
problematic for an exempt cooperative if
one of the dealers with which the
cooperative has large non-cleared
positions defaults, or if groups of
members whose financial strength may
be highly correlated and whose
aggregate non-cleared positions with the
cooperative are large, encounter
financial challenges. In this way, the
credit risk of one of the cooperative’s
counterparties could adversely impact
the other counterparties of that
cooperative.
Conversely, if an exempt cooperative
becomes insolvent and its positions
with a SD or MSP are substantial, it is
possible that its non-cleared positions
could be large enough to exacerbate
instability at the SD or MSP or could
create greater risk exposure for the
members with which the cooperative
entered into swaps.
The FCC stated that because FCS
institutions have collateral agreements
in place, ‘‘clearing offers very little
additional protection to FCS
institutions.’’ The Commission
acknowledges that counterparty risk can
be mitigated through collateral
arrangements, but also notes that the
extent to which counterparty risk is
reduced through collateral agreements
depends on the amount of collateral
required from each party to the swap,
the liquidity of that collateral in stressed
market conditions, the frequency with
which the amount of collateral is
adjusted to account for variations in the
value of the swap or the collateral, and
the ability of the non-defaulting party to
claim the collateral quickly in the event
that their counterparty defaults.80 The
Commission does not have adequate
information to determine how
effectively collateral arrangements may
mitigate counterparty risk born by
exempt cooperatives and their
counterparties in the absence of central
clearing.
3. Costs and Benefits for Other Market
Participants
The ABA commented that the
Commission did not consider
competitive harm to banks when
analyzing the costs and benefits of the
cooperative exemption. The ABA and
ICBA commented that cooperatives
compete with banks for the same
business opportunities and provide
similar services. They further stated that
the exemption would provide
cooperatives with a competitive
80 The 2012 ISDA Margin Survey indicates that
71% of all OTC derivatives transactions were
subject to collateral agreements during 2011, but
notes that the degree of collateralization may vary
significantly depending on the type of derivative
and counterparties entering into a transaction.
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:26 Aug 21, 2013
Jkt 229001
advantage because they ‘‘would have
more liquidity available for lending than
comparable banks would and be able to
provide lower cost funding.’’ Further,
the ABA stated that ‘‘the competitive
impact of the proposed exemption
would grow as more cooperatives
increase their swaps portfolios to take
advantage of the pricing and other
economic benefits it affords.’’
The Commission recognizes that the
cooperative exemption may provide
clearing cost savings related benefits to
eligible cooperatives with assets in
excess of $10 billion.81 However, in
assessing the competitive costs and
benefits of the cooperative exemption
the Commission believes the policy
considerations for establishing
cooperatives also need to be taken into
account. As described section IV,
Congress and the states have established
the cooperative legal structure distinct
from other corporate forms to facilitate
the economic advantage of cooperative
action for the mutual benefit of a
cooperative’s members. The cooperative
exemption provides the members with
the benefits of the end-user exception,
both directly and indirectly through
their cooperatives, without having to
switch from doing business with their
existing cooperatives to doing business
with small financial institutions or other
entities that can elect to exempt their
swaps from clearing, but which are not
organized for the specific purpose of
benefitting those members. The
cooperative exemption furthers these
benefits by recognizing that the
cooperatives were established to act on
behalf of their members in the
marketplace and providing an
exemption from clearing to eligible
cooperatives. In effect, the cooperative
exemption ensures that the existing
members of exempt cooperatives can
achieve the full benefits of both
cooperative action and of the end-user
exception.
4. Costs and Benefits to the Public
The public generally has an interest in
mandatory clearing because of its
potential to reduce counterparty risk
among large, interconnected
institutions, and to facilitate rapid
resolution of outstanding positions held
by such institutions in the event of their
default. By narrowly crafting the
81 The Commission notes, however, that most
small banks are also eligible for the end-user
exception, which can be elected for a wider range
of swaps than the cooperative exemption. Section
50.50(d) of the Commission’s regulations provides
that banks, FCS institutions, and credit unions that
have total assets of $10 billion or less are eligible
for the end-user exception with certain
exceptions—primarily that they not be SDs or
MSPs.
PO 00000
Frm 00018
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
proposed cooperative exemption to
incorporate qualifying criteria limiting
both the types of institutions and the
types of swaps that are eligible, the
Commission has sought to conserve this
public interest.
The ABA and the ICBA commented
that the four FCS banks and FCS
lending associations are jointly and
severally liable for one another, and that
‘‘the aggregated asset size of these
institutions is $230 billion and growing
rapidly.’’ The ICBA also stated that the
financial cooperatives affected by the
exemption will grow larger over time
and may present a systemic risk in the
future. The ABA stated that because the
FCS is a GSE, it is a potential liability
to U.S. taxpayers. The CUNA, on the
other hand, asserted that the exemption
would not have significant impact on
the overall swap market because of the
small number of entities eligible for the
exemption. Similarly, the FCC stated
that because of collateral agreements
that FCS institutions have in place that
‘‘the FCS poses no systemic risk to the
U.S. financial system.’’
The Commission acknowledges that
the magnitude of risk and potential
costs to the public created by an
exemption from clearing depends on
several factors including: The number
and size of the exempt cooperatives
electing the exemption; the size,
number, and type of exempt swaps held
by each institution; the risks inherent in
their outstanding swaps; the
concentration of swaps with individual
counterparties; the financial strength of
counterparties to exempt swaps; and the
presence of collateral agreements related
to the exempt swaps.82 The Commission
has limited data with which to evaluate
these factors. Commenters provided
limited data, noting the size of the four
farm credit banks 83 and the number and
size of certain credit unions with more
than $10 billion in assets.84 However,
commenters did not provide, and the
Commission does not have, detailed
data regarding the size of exempt
cooperatives’ non-cleared swaps,
information regarding the concentration
82 As noted above, the ability of collateral
agreements to mitigate counterparty risk and risk to
the public depends on the details of those
agreements with regard to the amount and quality
of collateral required, the frequency with which it
is adjusted to reflect changing valuations, and the
speed with which the non-defaulting party can
claim the collateral in the event that their
counterparty defaults.
83 ABA stated that the four Farm Credit banks
have approximately $15 billion, $29 billion, $76
billion, and $90 billion in assets.
84 ABA stated that there are four credit unions
with more than $10 billion in assets and are likely
to be several more within the next year. They also
stated that one credit union has nearly $50 billion
in assets and another has more than $25 billion.
E:\FR\FM\22AUR2.SGM
22AUR2
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 163 / Thursday, August 22, 2013 / Rules and Regulations
tkelley on DSK3SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
of non-cleared positions with particular
counterparties, or information regarding
the financial strength of those
counterparties. In addition, while
commenters noted the potential for
collateral agreements to mitigate
counterparty risk in the absence of
clearing, they did not provide data or
additional information regarding the
agreements that they anticipate will be
used. Each of these factors could have
a significant bearing on how much risk
is created for the public by exempting
eligible counterparties from the clearing
requirement.
Notwithstanding the limited data
available, the Commission considered
the potential risks that could arise from
cooperatives entering into non-cleared
swaps and the Commission believes it
has mitigated these risks with the
conditions imposed in the rule that
limit the number of entities and types of
swaps eligible for the cooperative
exemption. These conditions are
described in sections I, II and II above.
In addition, the Commission notes
that cooperatives that may qualify as
exempt cooperatives are supervised by
other regulators that have access to more
detailed information regarding the
swaps executed by the cooperatives and
that are likely to have additional
information regarding the risk factors
discussed above. These regulators can
monitor the use of swaps by these
cooperatives and the risk factors related
to that swap activity. Using this
information, these regulators can assess
the risks related to the non-cleared
swaps in the context of the overall
regulatory framework applicable to the
cooperatives and the changing financial
condition of the cooperatives and in that
context address the potential systemic
risk with the cooperatives using their
regulatory authority.
Finally, while it is important to
consider the potential risks noted above,
it is also important to assess the benefits
provided by the cooperative exemption.
The Commission believes ensuring that
the members of exempt cooperatives can
continue to use their cooperatives in the
manner intended and also realize the
full benefits of the end-user exception
through their cooperatives is
appropriate given the unique nature of
cooperatives and the statutory and
policy considerations discussed above
in section III.
D. Costs and Benefits Compared to
Alternatives
There were several alternatives
proposed by commenters that the
Commission considered including:
Providing a ‘‘ride along’’ exemption for
community banks larger than $10
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:26 Aug 21, 2013
Jkt 229001
billion; and including cooperatives with
members that are financial entities,
either with or without additional
restrictions on the eligibility of swaps
conducted by such cooperatives.
The Commission considered a ‘‘ridealong’’ provision, proposed by the ICBA,
which would provide a clearing
exemption for community banks that
exceed the $10 billion total assets
threshold. Providing a ‘‘ride-along’’
provision could mitigate the potential
competitive effects of the exception, as
alleged by the ICBA, but would also
increase the potential risk to the public
by increasing the number of large
financial entities eligible for an
exemption from clearing.
Moreover, expanding the exemption
in this way could also make it possible
for SDs, MSPs, and other large financial
institutions to avoid clearing by using
exempt community banks as an
intermediary for their swap
transactions. Finally, allowing noncooperatives to use the exemption
would not reflect the unique structure of
cooperatives that is the basis for the
exemption and result in an expansion of
the small financial institution
exemption beyond the parameters
detailed in the final release for the
Commissions regulations implementing
the end-user exception.85 For these
reasons, the Commission has
determined not to include the suggested
‘‘ride-along’’ provision.
The ICBA also stated that the
cooperative exemption does not include
the FHL Banks, and that thousands of
small banks that are members of the
FHL Bank system will be disadvantaged
by the cooperative exemption because
the FHL Banks will not be able to
provide the same or similar low cost
financing to community banks as FCS
lenders do for their cooperative
associations. The ICBA and the FHL
Banks commented that the FHL Banks
should be included as exempt
cooperatives either generally, or to the
extent they provide services to their
members that qualify for the small
financial institution exemption from the
definition of financial entity.
In the NPRM, the Commission
considered including cooperatives
consisting of members that could not
elect the end-user exception, as
suggested by the FHL Banks. Such an
exemption would assist in ensuring that
a greater number of cooperatives are
able to elect not to clear swaps.
However, as described in greater detail
in section III, if the cooperatives elected
the exemption when transacting with or
for the benefit of members that are not
85 77
PO 00000
FR 42559 (Jul. 19, 2012).
Frm 00019
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
52303
eligible for the end-user exception (i.e.
financial institutions with total assets
greater than $10 billion) it could
significantly increase the number of
swaps that are exempt from the clearing
requirement and result in exemptions
for entities that Congress has not
provided any indication should be
exempt from the clearing requirement.86
If the cooperative exemption were
expanded in this way, it would reduce
the benefits derived from required
clearing. By contrast, with the limiting
conditions included in the cooperative
exemption rule, the Commission is
ensuring that the exemption is only
available to cooperatives whose
members can elect the end-user
exception or are themselves
cooperatives whose members can elect
the end-user exception.87
The FHL Banks suggested that this
problem could be addressed by limiting
the exemption to swaps that hedge risks
associated with loans to eligible
members. However, allowing new or
existing cooperatives with financial
entity members to elect not to clear
swaps related to activities with
members that are eligible for the enduser exception would dilute the benefits
that qualifying members achieve
through the exemption thereby
undermining the purpose for the
exemption. For example, as described
above in section III, if the FHL Banks
elect the cooperative exemption only for
swaps related to members who qualify
as small financial institutions, the
decision not to clear those swaps could
create clearing cost savings for the FHL
Banks. Those savings would increase
the capital that the FHL Banks distribute
or allocate to their members as part of
the full member pro rata patronage
distribution. If larger members hold a
large ownership stake in the
cooperative, those members would also
receive a proportionately large share of
the distributions, including a
proportionately large share of the
savings that result from the cooperative
86 Note, for example, that while the FHL Banks
have thousands of members that qualify for the
small financial institution exemption and who
therefor can elect the end-user exception, over one
hundred members of the FHL Banks would not
qualify because they are financial entities with total
assets in excess of $10 billion. These members
include some of the largest financial entities in the
United States. In addition, as described above in
section III, financial entities with assets in excess
of $10 billion have borrowed more than half the
amount lent by the FHL banks to members.
87 The Commission notes that banks and other
entities that qualify for the small financial
institution exemption from the financial entity
definition are not excluded under the regulation
from being members of exempt cooperatives.
E:\FR\FM\22AUR2.SGM
22AUR2
tkelley on DSK3SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
52304
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 163 / Thursday, August 22, 2013 / Rules and Regulations
exemption.88 In other words, members
that are eligible for the end-user
exception would not receive the full
benefits of the exemption that is
extended to the cooperative. By
contrast, with the limiting conditions
included in the cooperative exemption
rule, the Commission is ensuring that
the exemption is only available to
cooperatives whose members could all
elect the end-user exception or are
themselves cooperatives whose
members could elect the end-user
exception, and thus the additional prorata patronage distributions that an
exempt cooperative makes because of
the cooperative exemption will only go
to such entities.
The FCC requested clarification with
respect to the Commission’s view on
what swaps are ‘‘related to’’ a
cooperative’s loans to its members, and
advocated a broad interpretation. They
also stated that ‘‘clarification of these
items will serve to increase the
likelihood that the System’s farmer and
rancher member borrowers will be able
to benefit from this proposed exemption
from clearing.’’ The broader
interpretation requested by the FCC
could increase the number of swaps that
are eligible for the exemption by
including swaps that serve non-member
related purposes, which would further
reduce clearing-related costs for eligible
cooperatives, but would also increase
the counterparty risk that eligible
cooperatives and their counterparties
bear due to decreased clearing. In the
Commission’s view, this broader
exemption is not justified given the
rationale behind the cooperative
exemption. As stated above, the term
‘‘related to’’ is intended to include
swaps that the exempt cooperatives may
enter into with non-members to hedge
or mitigate the risks incurred by the
cooperatives related to their member
lending activities. For example, where
cooperatives obtain wholesale funding,
only the portion of funding that is not
used to make non-member loans may be
hedged with exempt swaps.89 By
limiting the eligibility of exempt
cooperatives’ swaps in this way, the
Commission reduces the counterparty
risk that exempt cooperatives and their
counterparties could experience due to
decreased clearing.
88 See section II above for a full discussion of the
relative benefits available to different sized
members of the FHL Banks.
89 See section III.C above.
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:26 Aug 21, 2013
Jkt 229001
E. Section 15(a) Factors
1. Protection of Market Participants and
the Public
As described above, if exempt
cooperatives elect to exempt certain
swaps from required clearing, these
cooperatives may not need to pay DCO
and FCM clearing fees for clearing those
swaps. In addition, the exemption may
reduce the amount of capital that
exempt cooperatives must allocate to
margin accounts with their FCM. This,
in turn, provides benefits to the
members of exempt cooperatives, that
may otherwise absorb such costs as they
are passed on by the cooperatives to
their members in the form of fees, less
desirable spreads on swaps or loans
conducted with the cooperative, or
lower member allocated capital or
patronage distributions.
The exemption will create certain
reporting costs for eligible entities.
However, as described in the
rulemaking for the end-user exception
where the specific reporting
requirements were addressed, the
reporting required uses a simple checkthe-box approach and elective annual
reporting of certain information that
should minimize per swap reporting
costs, particularly for cooperatives that
enter into multiple swaps.
The exemption is narrowly tailored to
exempt only a relatively small number
of institutions and to include only
swaps that are associated with positions
established in connection with
originating loans made to customers, or
that hedge or mitigate risk arising in
connection with such member loans or
swaps. These limitations will tend to
mitigate the risk to the public that could
result from the exemption.
In addition, this exemption is likely to
increase counterparty risk for
counterparties to exempted swaps as
well as for the exempted cooperatives.
However, as described above, exempted
cooperatives and their counterparties
may use collateral agreements with
exempted swaps to mitigate
counterparty risk.
2. Efficiency, Competitiveness, and
Financial Integrity of Swap Markets
While the cooperative exemption
would take swaps out of clearing, it
mitigates the impact on the financial
integrity of the swap markets by limiting
the types of entities and swaps that are
eligible. As discussed above, the
exemption is designed to include only
cooperatives that are made up entirely
of entities that could elect the end-user
exception, and only swaps associated
with loans between the cooperative and
such members.
PO 00000
Frm 00020
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
The exemption may have competitive
effects by allowing the members of
exempt cooperatives to achieve
additional benefits from the actions of
their cooperatives. The Commission
believes such benefits are consistent
with the intended public interests
served by the establishment of
cooperative structures as a separate legal
form by Congress and the states. The
Commission addresses these issues in
section IV and VI.C.3. Commenters did
not provide, and the Commission does
not have, information that is sufficient
to quantify the competitive effects that
will result from the exemption.
3. Price Discovery
Clearing, in general, encourages better
price discovery because it eliminates the
importance of counterparty
creditworthiness in pricing swaps
cleared through a given DCO. That is, by
making the counterparty
creditworthiness of all swaps of a
certain type essentially the same, prices
should reflect factors related to the
terms of the swap, rather than the
idiosyncratic risk posed by the entities
trading it.90 To the extent that the
cooperative exemption reduces the
number of swaps subject to required
clearing, it will lessen the beneficial
effects of required clearing for price
discovery. However, the Commission
anticipates that the number of swaps
eligible for this exemption, currently
estimated at approximately 500 a year,
will be a de minimis fraction of all those
that are otherwise required to be
cleared. Therefore, the Commission
believes that there will not be a material
impact on price discovery.
4. Sound Risk Management Practices
To the extent that a swap is removed
from clearing, all other things being
constant, it is a detriment to a sound
risk management regime. To the extent
that exempt cooperatives enter into noncleared swaps on the basis of this rule,
it likely increases the exposure of
exempt cooperatives and their
counterparties to counterparty credit
risk. For the public, it increases the risk
that financial distress at one or more
cooperatives could spread to other
financial institutions with which those
cooperatives have concentrated
positions. However, as discussed above,
this additional risk may be reduced by
the presence of bilateral margin
agreements, which the Commission
90 See Chen, K., et al. ‘‘An Analysis of CDS
Transactions: Implications for Public Reporting,’’
September 2011, Federal Reserve Bank of New York
Staff Reports, at 14.
E:\FR\FM\22AUR2.SGM
22AUR2
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 163 / Thursday, August 22, 2013 / Rules and Regulations
believes are often used in the absence of
clearing.
5. Other Public Interest Considerations
The Commission believes that the
cooperative exemption serves the public
interest by furthering the public benefits
cited by Congress and state legislatures
in legislation authorizing cooperative
business forms as discussed in section
IV above. The cooperative structure
allows the members to pool their
resources, achieve economies of scale,
and realize the benefits of acting in
markets through larger entities.
However, absent the cooperative
exemption, the exempt cooperatives
would be unable to elect the end-user
exception because the amount of their
assets precludes them from qualifying as
small financial institutions. In effect, the
cooperative structure, which is intended
to provide advantages to its memberowners by creating a large entity whose
mission is to serve their interests,
instead prevents the members from
receiving the full benefits of the enduser exception when using their large
cooperatives. The cooperative
exemption therefor is in the public
interest because it resolves a conflict
between the small financial institution
language of section 2(h)(7) of the CEA
and the general policy behind
establishing cooperatives of creating
large financial institutions with the
mission of serving the mutual interests
of their member-owners.
VII. Related Matters
tkelley on DSK3SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
A. Regulatory Flexibility Act
The Regulatory Flexibility Act
(‘‘RFA’’) requires that agencies consider
whether the rules they propose will
have a significant economic impact on
a substantial number of small entities 91
and, if so, provide a regulatory
flexibility analysis respecting the
impact.92 Regulation § 39.6(f) (now
§ 50.51) would affect cooperatives, their
members, and potentially the
counterparties with whom they trade.
These entities could be SDs, MSPs, and
eligible contract participants
(‘‘ECPs’’).93 Regulation § 39.6(f) (now
91 The Small Business Administration identifies
(by North American Industry Classification System
codes) a small business size standard of $7 million
or less in annual receipts for Subsector 523—
Securities, Commodity Contracts, and Other
Financial Investments and Related Activities. 13
CFR parts 1, 121.201.
92 5 U.S.C. 601 et seq.
93 It is possible that a cooperative or members
thereof may not be ECPs. However, pursuant to
Section 2(e) of the CEA, if a counterparty to a swap
is not an ECP, then such swap must be entered into
on, or subject to the rules of, a board of trade
designated as a contract market under Section 5 of
the CEA. All such swaps must be cleared by the
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:26 Aug 21, 2013
Jkt 229001
§ 50.51) would additionally affect SDRs.
As noted in the NPRM, the Commission
has previously determined that SDs,
MSPs, and SDRs are not small entities
for purposes of the RFA.94
It is possible that some members of
cooperatives may be small entities
under the RFA. For these members to be
impacted by the cooperative exemption
compliance requirements they would
have to be entering into swaps with the
exempt cooperative and the exemption
would need to be elected. In order for
two counterparties to a swap to enter
into a swap bilaterally, both parties
must be ECPs.95 Based on the definition
of ECP in the Commodity Futures
Modernization Act of 2000, and the
legislative history underlying that
definition, the Commission has
previously determined that ECPs should
not be small entities for purposes of the
RFA.96 The Commission has been made
aware in other contexts that some ECPs,
specifically those that do not fall within
a category of ECP that is subject to a
dollar threshold, may be small entities.
If there are cooperative members that
are both ECPs as defined in the CEA and
small entities for purposes of the RFA,
the exemption is nevertheless most
likely to provide an economic benefit to
the cooperative member. Furthermore, if
elected, the cooperative exemption
would impose the same or similar costs
of compliance on members that the
previously adopted end-user exception
from the clearing requirement imposes.
The end-user exception provides
effectively the same type of relief from
clearing. Accordingly, the cooperative
exemption does not create any
materially new or different compliance
costs than similar regulations that were
previously adopted. Finally, the
cooperative exemption is elective. If a
member that is a small entity wanted to
clear its swap, the cooperative
exemption does not require them to
enter into swaps with their cooperatives
and they could execute swaps with
other parties that would agree to
clearing. Accordingly, the cooperative
exemption would not cause any new
significant economic impact on these
members.
The Chairman, on behalf of the
Commission, certified in the NPRM,
pursuant to 5 U.S.C. 605(b), that
§ 39.6(f) (now § 50.51(a)) will not have
board of trade. See section 5(d)(11) of the CEA, 7
U.S.C. 7(d)(11). In effect all swaps entered into by
a cooperative or a member that is not an ECP will
need to be executed on a board of trade and
therefore will be cleared.
94 See 77 FR 30596, 30701 (May 23, 2012); see
also 75 FR 80898, 80926 (Dec. 23, 2010).
95 7 U.S.C. 2(e).
96 See 66 FR 20740, 20743 (Apr. 25, 2001).
PO 00000
Frm 00021
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
52305
a significant impact on a substantial
number of small entities. The
Commission requested comment on this
decision in the NPRM.
The ICBA commented that the
proposal impacts a substantial number
of small community banks because they
are members of the FHL banks and the
FHL banks are not exempt cooperatives.
According to the ICBA, the small bank
members of the FHL bank system would
be disadvantaged because the FHL
banks will not be able to provide the
same or similar low cost financing to
community banks as FCS lenders will
for their cooperatives.
The Commission also received two
comments regarding the impact of
Regulation § 39.6(f) (now § 50.51(a)) on
the competition between banks that are
small entities and cooperatives that
elect the cooperative exemption.
According to the ABA, the
Commission’s analysis of the economic
impact on small entities did not
consider that economic impact on the
‘‘hundreds of end-user banks that are
competing with cooperatives for the
same business opportunities.’’
Similarly, the ICBA commented that the
‘‘competitive advantages afforded to
large credit unions and large FCS
funding banks . . . would allow these
institutions advantages in competing
directly against small community banks
even if they have a small financial
institution exemption.’’ The ICBA then
referenced CoBank as an example of an
FCS funding bank with a wide
geographic footprint over two dozen
states that could grow larger.
The ABA and the ICBA asserted that
the Commission is obliged under the
RFA to consider the impact of the
regulation on small banks, including
small banks that are members of the
FHL bank system. Specifically,
commenters asserted that the
Commission should consider the
competitive benefit the cooperative
exemption might give to exempt
cooperatives as compared to small
banks that might be small entities for
purposes of the RFA both on their own
and because small banks are members of
the FHL bank system.97 The
Commission has applied the RFA to
entities that are cooperatives who may
elect the cooperative exemption and
their members. Small community banks
that are not members of exempt
cooperatives are not subject to the
cooperative exemption. The
Commission also notes that, as
discussed above, to the extent a small
97 The FHL banks would not qualify for the
cooperative exemption because they have large
financial entity members. See section IV above.
E:\FR\FM\22AUR2.SGM
22AUR2
52306
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 163 / Thursday, August 22, 2013 / Rules and Regulations
tkelley on DSK3SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
community bank is or becomes a
member of an exempt cooperative and
enters into a swap bilaterally with an
exempt cooperative for which the
cooperative exemption is elected, that
member would have to be an ECP, in
order to enter into the swap bilaterally,
and also an entity that could elect the
end-user exception. Accordingly, the
Commission continues to believe that
the cooperative exemption will not have
a significant economic impact on small
entities.
Therefore, the Chairman, on behalf of
the Commission, hereby certifies,
pursuant to 5 U.S.C. 605(b), that the
final regulation would not have a
significant economic impact on a
substantial number of small entities.
B. Paperwork Reduction Act
Regulation § 39.6(f)(3) (now
§ 50.51(c)) requires a cooperative to
conform with certain reporting
conditions if it elects the cooperative
exemption. These new requirements
constitute a collection of information
within the meaning of the Paperwork
Reduction Act of 1995 (‘‘PRA’’).98
Under the PRA, an agency may not
conduct or sponsor, and a person is not
required to respond to, a collection of
information unless it has been approved
by the Office of Management and
Budget (‘‘OMB’’) and displays a
currently valid control number.99 This
rulemaking contains new collections of
information for which the Commission
must seek a valid control number. The
Commission therefore requested that
OMB assign a control number and OMB
assigned control number 3038–0102 for
this new collection of information. The
Commission has also submitted the
proposed rulemaking, this final rule
release, and supporting documentation
to OMB for review in accordance with
44 U.S.C. 3507(d) and 5 CFR 1320.11.
The title for these new collections of
information is ‘‘Rule 39.6(f) Cooperative
Clearing Exemption Notification.’’
Responses to these information
collections will be mandatory if the
cooperative exemption is elected.
With respect to all of the
Commission’s collections, the
Commission will protect proprietary
information according to the Freedom of
Information Act and 17 CFR part 145,
‘‘Commission Records and
Information.’’ In addition, section
8(a)(1) of the Act strictly prohibits the
Commission, unless specifically
authorized by the Act, from making
public ‘‘data and information that
would separately disclose the business
98 44
U.S.C. 3501 et seq.
99 Id.
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:26 Aug 21, 2013
Jkt 229001
transactions or market positions of any
person and trade secrets or names of
customers.’’ The Commission also is
required to protect certain information
contained in a government system of
records according to the Privacy Act of
1974, 5 U.S.C. 552a.
1. Information To Be Provided by
Reporting Parties
For each swap where the exemption
is elected, either the cooperative, or its
counterparty if the counterparty is an
SD or MSP, must report: (1) That the
election of the exemption is being made;
(2) which party is the electing
counterparty; and (3) certain
information specific to the electing
counterparty unless that information
has already been provided by the
electing counterparty through an annual
filing. As noted in the NPRM, the third
set of information comprises data that is
likely to remain relatively constant for
many, but not all, electing
counterparties and therefore, does not
require swap-by-swap reporting and can
be reported less frequently. In addition,
for entities registered with the SEC, the
reporting party will also be required to
report: (1) The SEC filer’s central index
key number; and (2) that an appropriate
committee of the board of directors has
approved the decision for that entity to
enter into swaps that are exempt from
the requirements of section 2(h)(1)(A) of
the CEA.
Exempt cooperatives entering into
swaps with members and electing the
exemption will likely be responsible to
report this information. When
cooperatives enter into swaps with SDs
or MSPs, the SDs or MSPs will be
responsible for reporting the
information, but cooperatives would
bear some costs related to the personnel
hours committed to reporting the
required information.
As discussed in the NPRM, for
purposes of estimating the cost of
reporting in connection with the
cooperative exemption, the Commission
estimated that each of the ten exempt
cooperatives would enter into 50 swaps
per year on average. Accordingly, the
Commission estimated that exempt
cooperatives would elect the
cooperative exemption for 500 swaps
each year. The reporting cost estimates
are discussed separately below
according to each requirement.
The Commission invited public
comment on any aspect of the reporting
burdens discussed in the NPRM. The
Commission received two comments on
the Commission’s approach to
calculating the estimated cost burdens.
The ABA questioned whether the
Commission had underestimated its
PO 00000
Frm 00022
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
estimations of the number of
cooperatives eligible for the exemption,
and the number of swaps each eligible
cooperative engages in per year. The
ABA also commented that the figures
used are static and as such do not allow
for potential future growth in the
number of potential exempt
cooperatives and number of swaps in
which they may transact. The ICBA
similarly commented on the static
nature Commission’s approach, and
noted that the approach does not
account for future growth when the use
of swaps in the OTC market has grown
significantly in recent years.
Furthermore, the ICBA noted that the
CFTC looked at information from five of
the ten estimated cooperatives that may
be eligible for the cooperative
exemption, but did not indicate which
of the five cooperatives it considered or
what the reason was for not reviewing
information from the other five
cooperatives.
In response to the comments received,
the Commission notes that the
commenters provided no data or other
information to support their assertions
that the number of cooperatives and the
number of swaps that may be eligible for
the cooperative exemption may be low
or inaccurate. The summary information
regarding swap activities of five
prospective exempt cooperatives was
provided to the Commission on a
voluntary basis through the FCC and
CFC. Based on discussions with these
entities, the Commission believes that
these five cooperatives were more active
than the other potential exempt
cooperatives in using swaps and
therefore this sampling of information
was appropriate for estimating the
number of swaps executed by the ten
potential exempt cooperatives identified
by the Commission. Subsequent to
receipt of the comments on the NPRM,
the Commission contacted the
regulators for FCS cooperatives and
federal credit unions and these
regulators expressed a view that the
Commission’s estimates were not
inappropriate.
In response to the comments that the
estimates represent only a current snap
shot of activity, the Commission
recognizes that the number of entities
eligible for the exemption and the
number of swaps per eligible
cooperative is likely to change in the
future and that the benefits of this
exemption for exempt cooperatives
could encourage more exempt
cooperatives to use swaps and could
increase the number of swaps used by
those cooperatives. However, the
Commission notes that whether such
growth is realized also depends on
E:\FR\FM\22AUR2.SGM
22AUR2
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 163 / Thursday, August 22, 2013 / Rules and Regulations
additional factors that the Commission
does not have adequate information to
evaluate such as: (1) Subsequent
changes to laws or regulations affecting
one or more types of cooperatives and
the extent to which they may use swaps;
(2) increases or decreases in the total
amount of borrowing undertaken by the
members of those cooperatives; and (3)
the frequency with which exempt
cooperatives make the types of loans or
experience other business changes that
might increase or decrease the use of
swaps. It is not possible to evaluate how
future changes in these factors are likely
to affect the number of swaps for which
the cooperative exemption may be
elected. Accordingly, the Commission
believes using a static estimate is
reasonable.
tkelley on DSK3SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
a. Regulation § 39.6(f)(3) (now
§ 50.51(c)): Reporting Requirements
Regulation § 39.6(f)(3) (now
§ 50.51(c)) requires exempt cooperatives
that are reporting counterparties to
comply with the reporting requirements
of § 50.50(b), which require delivering
specific information to a registered SDR
or, if no SDR is available, the
Commission. An exempt cooperative
that is the reporting counterparty would
have to report the information required
in § 50.50(b)(1)(i) and (ii) for each swap
for which it elects the cooperative
exemption.
As discussed in the NPRM, the
Commission anticipates that to comply
with § 50.50(b)(1)(i) and (ii), each
reporting counterparty would be
required to check one box in the SDR or
Commission reporting data fields
indicating that the exempt cooperative
is electing not to clear the swap. The
Commission estimated that the cost of
complying with this requirement for
each reporting counterparty to be
between less than $1 and $7 for each
transaction, or approximately $300 to
$3,500 per year for all transactions.
The Commission did not receive any
comments concerning the cost to
exempt cooperatives from complying
with § 50.50(b)(1)(i) and (ii).
b. Regulation § 50.50(b)(1)(iii): Annual
Reporting Option
Regulation 50.50(b)(1)(iii) allows for
certain counterparty specific
information identified therein to be
reported either swap-by-swap by the
reporting counterparty or annually by
the electing counterparty. As discussed
in the NPRM, the Commission
anticipates that the exempt cooperatives
will make annual filings of the
information required. The Commission
estimated the annual per cooperative
cost for the filing to be between $200
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:26 Aug 21, 2013
Jkt 229001
and $590, or $2,000 to $5,900 as the
aggregate cost for all exempt
cooperatives.
The Commission did not receive any
comments concerning the cost to
exempt cooperatives for electing the
annual reporting option under
§ 50.50(b)(1)(iii).
c. Updating Reporting Procedures
As discussed in the NPRM, the
Commission anticipates that
cooperatives electing the exemption that
are reporting counterparties may need to
modify their reporting systems to
accommodate the additional data fields
required by the rule. The Commission
estimated that the modifications to
comply with § 39.6(f)(3) (now § 50.51(c))
would likely cost each reporting
counterparty between $340 and $3,400,
with the aggregate one-time cost for all
potential exempt cooperatives to be
$3,400 to $34,100.
The Commission did not receive any
comments concerning the cost to
exempt cooperatives in updating their
reporting systems to comply with
§ 39.6(f)(3) (now § 50.51(c)).
d. Burden on Non-Reporting
Cooperatives
As discussed in the NPRM, when an
exempt cooperative is not functioning as
the reporting counterparty (i.e., when
transacting with an SD or MSP), the
Commission anticipated that it may, at
certain times, need to communicate
information to its reporting
counterparties in order to facilitate
reporting. This information might
include whether the exempt cooperative
has filed an annual report pursuant to
§ 50.50(b), and information to facilitate
any due diligence that the reporting
counterparty may conduct. The
Commission estimated that a nonreporting exempt cooperative would
incur an annual aggregate cost for
communicating information to the
reporting counterparty between $400
and $39,000.100
The Commission did not receive any
comments concerning the cost a nonreporting exempt cooperative will incur
in communicating information to the
reporting counterparty.
List of Subjects in 17 CFR Part 50
Business and industry, Clearing,
Cooperatives, Reporting requirements,
Swaps.
Accordingly, the CFTC amends 17
CFR part 50 as follows:
100 The Commission noted the wide range in this
estimation, but explained the range could not be
narrowed given the unknowns associated with the
cost estimate.
PO 00000
Frm 00023
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
52307
PART 50—CLEARING REQUIREMENT
AND RELATED RULES
1. The authority citation for part 50
continues to read as follows:
■
Authority: 7 U.S.C. 2 and 7a–1 as
amended by Pub. L. 111–203, 124 Stat. 1376.
■
2. Add § 50.51 to read as follows:
§ 50.51
Exemption for Cooperatives.
Exemption for cooperatives. Exempt
cooperatives may elect not to clear
certain swaps identified in paragraph (b)
of this section that are otherwise subject
to the clearing requirement of section
2(h)(1)(A) of the Act if the following
requirements are satisfied.
(a) For the purposes of this paragraph,
an exempt cooperative means a
cooperative:
(1) Formed and existing pursuant to
Federal or state law as a cooperative;
(2) That is a ‘‘financial entity,’’ as
defined in section 2(h)(7)(C)(i) of the
Act, solely because of section
2(h)(7)(C)(i)(VIII) of the Act; and
(3) Each member of which is not a
‘‘financial entity,’’ as defined in section
2(h)(7)(C)(i) of the Act, or if any member
is a financial entity solely because of
section 2(h)(7)(C)(i)(VIII) of the Act,
such member is:
(i) Exempt from the definition of
‘‘financial entity’’ pursuant to
§ 50.50(d); or
(ii) A cooperative formed under
Federal or state law as a cooperative and
each member thereof is either not a
‘‘financial entity,’’ as defined in section
2(h)(7)(C)(i) of the Act, or is exempt
from the definition of ‘‘financial entity’’
pursuant to § 50.50(d).
(b) An exempt cooperative may elect
not to clear a swap that is subject to the
clearing requirement of section
2(h)(1)(A) of the Act if the swap:
(1) Is entered into with a member of
the exempt cooperative in connection
with originating a loan or loans for the
member, which means the requirements
of § 1.3(ggg)(5)(i), (ii), and (iii) are
satisfied; provided that, for this
purpose, the term ‘‘insured depository
institution’’ as used in those sections is
replaced with the term ‘‘exempt
cooperative’’ and the word ‘‘customer’’
is replaced with the word ‘‘member;’’ or
(2) Hedges or mitigates commercial
risk, in accordance with § 50.50(c),
related to loans to members or arising
from a swap or swaps that meet the
requirements of paragraph (b)(1) of this
section.
(c) An exempt cooperative that elects
the exemption provided in this section
shall comply with the requirements of
§ 50.50(b). For this purpose, the exempt
cooperative shall be the ‘‘electing
E:\FR\FM\22AUR2.SGM
22AUR2
52308
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 163 / Thursday, August 22, 2013 / Rules and Regulations
BILLING CODE 6351–01–P
investment company updates its
prospectus as described in Section II.F.,
below, and files the prospectus with the
SEC. Moreover, the publication of these
rules trigger the conditional compliance
date that was established in the
Commodity Pool Operators and
Commodity Trading Advisors:
Compliance Obligations rulemaking. 77
FR 11252, 11252 (Feb. 24, 2012). With
the publication of these rules, registered
CPOs of RICs must comply with § 4.27
on or before October 21, 2013.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
Amanda Lesher Olear, Associate
Director, Telephone: (202) 418–5283,
Email: aolear@cftc.gov, or Michael
Ehrstein, Attorney-Advisor, Telephone:
202–418–5957, Email: mehrstein@
cftc.gov, Division of Swap Dealer and
Intermediary Oversight, Commodity
Futures Trading Commission, Three
Lafayette Centre, 1155 21st Street NW.,
Washington, DC 20581.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION:
COMMODITY FUTURES TRADING
COMMISSION
I. Background
This rulemaking is related to the final
rule adopted under RIN 3038–AD30.
counterparty,’’ as such term is used in
§ 50.50(b), and for purposes of
§ 50.50(b)(1)(iii)(A), the reporting
counterparty, as determined pursuant to
§ 45.8, shall report that an exemption is
being elected in accordance with this
section.
Issued in Washington, DC, on August 13,
2013, by the Commission.
Melissa D. Jurgens,
Secretary of the Commission.
Note: The following appendix will not
appear in the Code of Federal Regulations.
Appendix to Clearing Exemption for
Certain Swaps Entered Into by
Cooperatives—Commission Voting
Summary
Appendix 1—Commission Voting Summary
On this matter, Chairman Gensler and
Commissioners Chilton, O’Malia, and Wetjen
voted in the affirmative.
[FR Doc. 2013–19945 Filed 8–21–13; 8:45 am]
17 CFR Part 4
RIN 3038–AD75
Harmonization of Compliance
Obligations for Registered Investment
Companies Required To Register as
Commodity Pool Operators
Commodity Futures Trading
Commission.
ACTION: Final rule.
AGENCY:
The Commodity Futures
Trading Commission (‘‘Commission’’ or
‘‘CFTC’’) is adopting final regulations
with respect to certain compliance
obligations for commodity pool
operators (‘‘CPOs’’) of investment
companies registered under the
Investment Company Act of 1940
(‘‘registered investment companies’’ or
‘‘RICs’’) that are required to register due
to the recent amendments to its
regulations. The Commission is also
adopting amendments to certain
provisions of part 4 of the Commission’s
regulations that are applicable to all
CPOs and Commodity Trading Advisors
(‘‘CTAs’’).
DATES: Effective dates: This rule is
effective August 22, 2013, except the
amendments to §§ 4.7(b)(4), 4.12(c)(3)(i),
4.23, 4.26, and 4.36 which are effective
September 23, 2013.
Compliance dates: Registered CPOs
seeking exemption under these rules
shall be required to comply with the
conditions adopted in § 4.12(c)(3)(i)
when the associated registered
tkelley on DSK3SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
SUMMARY:
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:26 Aug 21, 2013
Jkt 229001
A. Recent Amendments to § 4.5 as
Applicable to RICs
The Commodity Exchange Act
(‘‘CEA’’) 1 provides the Commission
with the authority to require registration
of CPOs and CTAs,2 to exclude any
entity from registration as a CPO or
CTA,3 and to require ‘‘[e]very
commodity trading advisor and
commodity pool operator registered
under [the CEA] to maintain books and
records and file such reports in such
form and manner as may be prescribed
by the Commission.’’ 4 The Commission
also has the authority to ‘‘make and
promulgate such rules and regulations
as, in the judgment of the Commission,
are reasonably necessary to effectuate
the provisions or to accomplish any of
the purposes of [the CEA].’’ 5
In February 2012, the Commission
adopted modifications to the exclusions
from the definition of CPO that are
delineated in § 4.5 (‘‘2012 Final Rule’’).6
17
U.S.C. 1, et seq.
U.S.C. 6m.
3 7 U.S.C. 1a(11) and 1a(12).
4 7 U.S.C. 6n(3)(A). Under part 4 of the
Commission’s regulations, unless otherwise
provided by the Commission, entities registered as
CPOs have reporting obligations with respect to
their operated pools. See 17 CFR 4.22.
5 7 U.S.C. 12a(5).
6 17 CFR 4.5. See 77 FR 11252 (Feb. 24, 2012);
correction 77 FR 17328 (March 26, 2012). Prior to
this Amendment, all RICs, and the principals and
employees thereof, were excluded from the
definition of ‘‘commodity pool operator,’’ by virtue
of the RICs registration under the Investment
Company Act of 1940. The 2012 amendment to
27
PO 00000
Frm 00024
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
Specifically, the Commission amended
§ 4.5 to modify the exclusion from the
definition of ‘‘commodity pool
operator’’ for those entities that are
investment companies registered as
such with the Securities and Exchange
Commission (‘‘SEC’’) pursuant to the
Investment Company Act of 1940 (‘‘ ’40
Act’’).7 This modification amended the
terms of the exclusion available to CPOs
of RICs to include only those CPOs of
RICs that commit no more than a de
minimis portion of their assets to the
trading of commodity interests that do
not fall within the definition of bona
fide hedging and who do not market
themselves as a commodity pool or
other commodity investment.8 Pursuant
to this amendment, any such CPO of a
RIC that exceeds this level, or markets
itself as such, will no longer be
excluded from the definition of CPO.
Accordingly, except for those CPOs of
RICs who commit no more than a de
minimis portion of their assets to the
trading of commodity interests that do
not fall within the definition of bona
fide hedging and who do not market
themselves as a commodity pool or
other commodity investment, an
operator of a RIC that meets the
definition of ‘‘commodity pool
operator’’ under § 4.10(d) of the
Commission’s regulations and § 1a(11)
of the CEA must register as such with
the Commission.9
B. Harmonization Proposal
In response to the Commission’s
February 2011 proposal to amend the
§ 4.5 exclusion with respect to CPOs of
RICs,10 as well a staff roundtable held
on July 16, 2011 (‘‘Roundtable’’),11 and
meetings with interested parties, the
Commission received numerous
§ 4.5 maintained this exclusion for those RICs that
engage in a de minimis amount of non-bona fide
hedging commodity interest transactions. See id.
Specifically, the amendment to § 4.5 retained this
exclusion for RICs whose non-bona fide hedging
commodity interest transactions require aggregate
initial margin and premiums that do not exceed five
percent of the liquidation value of the qualifying
pool’s portfolio, or whose non-bona fide hedging
commodity interest transactions’ aggregate net
notional value does not exceed 100 percent of the
liquidation value of the pool’s portfolio.
7 15 U.S.C. 80a–1, et seq. ‘‘SEC’’ as used herein
means the Securities and Exchange Commission or
its staff, as the context requires.
8 17 CFR 1.3(yy).
9 Pursuant to the terms of § 4.14(a)(4), CPOs are
not required to register as CTAs if the CPOs’
commodity trading advice is directed solely to, and
for the sole use of, the pool or pools for which they
are registered as CPOs. 17 CFR 4.14(a)(4).
10 76 FR 7976 (Feb. 11, 2011).
11 See Notice of CFTC Staff Roundtable
Discussion on Proposed Changes to Registration
and Compliance Regime for Commodity Pool
Operators and Commodity Trading Advisors,
available at https://www.cftc.gov/PressRoom/Events/
opaevent_cftcstaff070611.
E:\FR\FM\22AUR2.SGM
22AUR2
Agencies
[Federal Register Volume 78, Number 163 (Thursday, August 22, 2013)]
[Rules and Regulations]
[Pages 52285-52308]
From the Federal Register Online via the Government Printing Office [www.gpo.gov]
[FR Doc No: 2013-19945]
[[Page 52285]]
Vol. 78
Thursday,
No. 163
August 22, 2013
Part III
Commodity Futures Trading Commission
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
17 CFR Parts 4 and 50
Clearing Exemption for Certain Swaps Entered Into by Cooperatives;
Harmonization of Compliance Obligations for Registered Investment
Companies Required To Register as Commodity Pool Operators; Final Rules
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 163 / Thursday, August 22, 2013 /
Rules and Regulations
[[Page 52286]]
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
COMMODITY FUTURES TRADING COMMISSION
17 CFR Part 50
RIN 3038-AD47
Clearing Exemption for Certain Swaps Entered Into by Cooperatives
AGENCY: Commodity Futures Trading Commission.
ACTION: Final rule.
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
SUMMARY: The Commodity Futures Trading Commission (``CFTC'' or
``Commission'') is adopting final regulations pursuant to its authority
under section 4(c) of the Commodity Exchange Act (``CEA'') allowing
cooperatives meeting certain conditions to elect not to submit for
clearing certain swaps that such cooperatives would otherwise be
required to submit for clearing in accordance with section 2(h)(1) of
the CEA.
DATES: Effective September 23, 2013.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: Brian O'Keefe, Deputy Director, 202-
418-5658, bokeefe@cftc.gov, Division of Clearing and Risk, or Erik F.
Remmler, Deputy Director, 202-418-7630, eremmler@cftc.gov, Division of
Swap Dealer and Intermediary Oversight, Commodity Futures Trading
Commission, Three Lafayette Centre, 1155 21st Street NW., Washington,
DC 20581.
I. Background
The CEA, as amended by Title VII of the Dodd-Frank Wall Street
Reform and Consumer Protection Act (the ``Dodd-Frank Act''),\1\
establishes a comprehensive new regulatory framework for swaps. The CEA
requires a swap: (1) To be submitted for clearing through a derivatives
clearing organization (``DCO'') if the Commission has determined that
the swap is required to be cleared, unless an exception or exemption to
the clearing requirement applies; (2) to be reported to a swap data
repository (``SDR'') or the Commission; and (3) if such swap is subject
to a clearing requirement, to be executed on a designated contract
market (``DCM'') or swap execution facility (``SEF''), unless no DCM or
SEF has made the swap available to trade.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1\ See Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection
Act, Public Law 111-203, 124 Stat. 1376 (2010).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Section 2(h)(1)(A) of the CEA establishes a clearing requirement
for swaps, providing that ``[i]t shall be unlawful for any person to
engage in a swap unless that person submits such swap for clearing to a
[DCO] that is registered under [the CEA] or a [DCO] that is exempt from
registration under [the CEA] if the swap is required to be cleared.''
\2\ However, section 2(h)(7)(A) of the CEA provides that the clearing
requirement of section 2(h)(1)(A) shall not apply to a swap if one of
the counterparties to the swap: ``(i) is not a financial entity; (ii)
is using swaps to hedge or mitigate commercial risk; and (iii) notifies
the Commission, in a manner set forth by the Commission, how it
generally meets its financial obligations associated with entering into
non-cleared swaps'' (referred to hereinafter as the ``end-user
exception'').\3\ The Commission has adopted Sec. 39.6 (now recodified
as Sec. 50.50 \4\) to implement certain provisions of section 2(h)(7).
Accordingly, any swap that is required to be cleared by the Commission
pursuant to section 2(h)(2) of the CEA must be submitted to a DCO for
clearing by the counterparties unless the conditions of Sec. 50.50 are
satisfied or another exemption adopted by the Commission applies.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\2\ See section 2(h)(1)(A) of the CEA, 7 U.S.C. 2(h)(1)(A).
\3\ See section 2(h)(7)(A) of the CEA, 7 U.S.C. 2(h)(7)(A).
\4\ 77 FR 74284 (Dec. 13, 2012). The Commission re-codified the
end-user exception regulations as Sec. 50.50 so that market
participants are able to locate all rules related to the clearing
requirement in one part of the Code of Federal Regulations. Because
of this re-codification, all citations thereto in this final release
will be to the sections as renumbered.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Congress adopted the end-user exception in section 2(h)(7) of the
CEA to permit certain non-financial entities to continue using non-
cleared swaps to hedge or mitigate risks associated with their
underlying businesses, such as manufacturing, energy exploration,
farming, transportation, or other commercial activities. Additionally,
in section 2(h)(7)(C)(ii) of the CEA, the Commission was directed to
``consider whether to exempt [from the definition of `financial
entity'] small banks, savings associations, farm credit system
institutions, and credit unions, including:
(I) Depository institutions with total assets of $10,000,000,000 or
less;
(II) farm credit system institutions with total assets of
$10,000,000,000 or less; or
(III) credit unions with total assets of $10,000,000,000 or less.''
In Sec. 50.50(d), the Commission identifies which financial
entities are small financial institutions and establishes an exemption
from the definition of ``financial entity'' for these small financial
institutions pursuant to section 2(h)(7)(C)(ii) (the ``small financial
institution exemption''). The small financial institution exemption
largely adopts the language of section 2(h)(7)(C)(ii) in providing for
an exemption from the definition of ``financial entity'' for the types
of section 2(h)(7)(C)(ii) institutions having total assets of $10
billion or less.
On December 23, 2010, the Commission published for public comment a
notice of proposed rulemaking (``end-user exception NPRM'') to
implement the end-user exception.\5\ Several parties that commented on
the end-user exception NPRM recommended that the Commission extend
relief from clearing to cooperatives.\6\ These commenters primarily
reasoned \7\ that the member ownership nature of cooperatives and the
fact that cooperatives act in the interests of members that are non-
financial entities or cooperatives whose members are non-financial
entities, justified allowing the cooperatives to also elect the end-
user exception. In effect, they proposed that because a cooperative
acts in the interests of its members when facing the larger financial
markets, the end-user exception that would be available to a
cooperative's members should also be available to the cooperative.
Accordingly, commenters asserted, if the members themselves could elect
the end-user exception, then the Commission should permit the
cooperatives to do so as well.\8\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\5\ See 75 FR 80747 (Dec. 23, 2010).
\6\ See, e.g., comments received on the end-user exception NPRM
from: Agricultural Leaders of Michigan (ALM), The Farm Credit
Council (FCC), Allegheny Electric Cooperative, Inc. (AEC), Garkane
Energy Cooperative, Inc. (GEC), National Council of Farmer
Cooperatives, Dairy Farmers of America, and National Rural Utilities
Cooperative Finance Corporation (CFC). Comments received on the end-
user exception NPRM can be found on the Commission's Web site at
https://comments.cftc.gov/PublicComments/CommentList.aspx?id=937.
\7\ Other reasons given for providing an exemption from clearing
to cooperatives, including risk considerations, are discussed below.
\8\ In addition to the comments received on the end-user
exception NPRM, the Commission notes that several Senators and
members of the House of Representatives have expressed similar
support in committee hearings for ensuring that the implementation
of the Dodd-Frank Act does not change the way financial cooperatives
operate in relation to their members. See, e.g., Oversight Hearing:
Implementation of Title VII of the Wall St. Reform and Consumer
Prot. Act Before the S. Comm. on Agric., 112th Cong. 18 (2011)
(statement of Sen. Debbie Stabenow, Chairwoman, S. Comm. on Agric.)
(``I just want to make sure that . . . you're saying or that you're
going to guarantee that the relationship between farmers and co-ops
will be preserved and that farmers will continue to have affordable
access to risk management tools.''); One Year Later--The Wall St.
Reform and Consumer Prot. Act: Hearing Before the S. Comm. on
Agric., 112th Cong. 14 (statement of Sen. Amy Klobuchar, Member, S.
Comm. on Agric.) (``I hope there is a way to uniquely define farmer
co-ops so they can continue to do the kinds of things that they
do.''); Derivatives Reform: the View from Main St.: Hearing Before
the H. Comm. on Agric., 112th Cong. 12 (2011) (statement of Rep.
Timothy Johnson, Member, H. Comm. on Agric.) (``I'm also concerned,
real concerned, representing an area, as a lot of us do, where rural
electric cooperatives, agricultural cooperatives, and all that are
an essential part of our being, critical, positive entities that
really do a whole lot for the infrastructure of this country. . . .
And I'm very concerned that we're treating, in many ways, and you
are, those cooperatives in a way almost identical to Goldman Sachs,
and I think that's--frankly, I think that fall[s] of its own
weight.''); The Commodity Futures Trading Comm'n 2012 Agenda:
Hearing Before the H. Comm. on Agric., 112th Cong. 13 (2012)
(statement of Rep. Rick Crawford, Member, H. Comm. on Agric.)
(``[Agricultural cooperatives provide] swaps to their members and
then enter into [another swap to offset that risk]. This is critical
to their ability to continue [to provide] hedging tools to member[s]
of their coops. . . . '').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
[[Page 52287]]
However, section 2(h)(7) of the CEA does not differentiate
cooperatives from other types of entities and therefore, cooperatives
that are ``financial entities,'' as defined in section 2(h)(7)(i) of
the CEA, are unable to elect the end-user exception unless they qualify
for the small financial institution exemption. Some commenters
recommended including cooperatives that are ``financial entities'' with
total assets in excess of $10 billion in the small financial
institution exemption.\9\ However, as explained in greater detail in
the final release for Sec. 50.50, section 2(h)(7)(C)(ii) of the CEA
focused on asset size and not on the structure of the financial entity.
Accordingly, only cooperatives that are financial entities with total
assets of $10 billion or less can qualify as small financial
institutions under the small financial institution exemption.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\9\ See, e.g., comments received on the end-user exception NPRM
from: FCC, CFC, AEC, ALM, and GEC.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Notwithstanding the foregoing, the Commission recognized that the
member-owner structure of cooperatives and the merits of effectively
allowing cooperatives to also use the end-user exception when acting in
the interests of their members, warranted consideration. Accordingly,
the Commission is using the authority provided in section 4(c) of the
CEA to finalize Sec. 50.51 (proposed as Sec. 39.6(f) \10\), to permit
cooperatives that meet certain qualifications to elect not to clear
certain swaps that are otherwise required to be cleared pursuant to
section 2(h)(1)(A) of the CEA (hereinafter referred to as the
``cooperative exemption''). Under section 4(c) of the CEA, the
Commission can subject such exemptive relief to appropriate terms and
conditions.\11\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\10\ For ease of reference, the Commission is re-codifying
proposed Sec. 39.6(f) as Sec. 50.51 so that market participants
are able to locate all rules related to the clearing requirement in
one part of the Code of Federal Regulations.
\11\ 7 U.S.C. 6(c)(1).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
On July 17, 2012, the Commission published for public comment a
notice of proposed rulemaking (``NPRM'') proposing the cooperative
exemption as Sec. 39.6(f) (now Sec. 50.51).\12\ The Commission
explained that cooperatives have a unique legal structure that
differentiates them from other legal business structures in terms of
how they are operated and who benefits from their activities. In a
cooperative, the members of the cooperative are the principal customers
of the cooperative and are also the owners of the cooperative.
Accordingly, the cooperatives exist to serve their member-owners and do
not act for their own profit.\13\ The member-owners of the cooperative
collectively have full control over the governance of the cooperative.
In a real sense, a cooperative is not separable from its member-owners.
The cooperative exists to act in the mutual interests of its member-
owners in the marketplace.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\12\ 77 FR 41940 (July 17, 2012).
\13\ For example, the CFC was formed as a nonprofit corporation
under the District of Columbia Cooperative Association Act of 1940
to arrange financing for its members and their patrons and for the
``primary and mutual benefit of the patrons of the Association and
their patrons, as ultimate consumers.'' CFC Articles of
Incorporation and Bylaws, Art. I, (last amended Mar. 1, 2005),
available at https://www.nrucfc.coop/content/dam/cfc_assets/public_tier/publicDocs/governance/CFCbylaws_3_11.pdf.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
As described in greater detail below in section II, some
cooperatives provide financial services to their members including
lending and providing swaps, and the cooperatives sometimes hedge or
mitigate risks associated with those lending activities with other
financial entities such as swap dealers (``SDs''). The memberships of
some of these cooperatives consist of entities that can each elect the
end-user exception when entering into a swap. However, the end-user
exception is unavailable to some of those cooperatives because they
fall within the definition of ``financial entity'' and have assets in
excess of $10 billion. Accordingly, if the cooperative members continue
to enter into loans and swaps with their cooperative, they would not
receive the full benefits of the end-user exception because the
cooperative would have to clear its swaps even though it is entering
into the swaps to offset the risks associated with financial activities
with its members or to hedge risks associated with wholesale borrowing
activities, the proceeds of which are used to fund member loans. In
effect, absent an exception from the clearing requirement for a
cooperative that is providing certain swap services to its members, the
cooperative structure would be unable--solely because the cooperative
is large and has substantial assets--to achieve the intended benefits
for its members who can elect the end-user exception. In light of the
foregoing, the Commission is exercising its authority under section
4(c) of the CEA to establish the cooperative exemption.
The Commission received approximately 25 comment letters and
Commission staff participated in approximately two ex parte meetings
concerning the cooperative exemption NPRM.\14\ The Commission
considered these comments in formulating the final regulations, as
discussed below.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\14\ All comments received in response to the cooperative
exemption NPRM can be viewed on the Commission's Web site at https://comments.cftc.gov/PublicComments/CommentList.aspx?id=1237.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
II. Financial Entity Cooperatives
In the NPRM, the Commission described the structure of cooperatives
that provide financial services to their members to provide context for
the underlying rationale for the proposed cooperative exemption. The
description provided in the NPRM is summarized below to facilitate an
understanding of the comments received and the Commission's responses
thereto.
Cooperatives that are ``financial entities,'' as defined in section
2(h)(7)(C)(i) of the CEA, generally serve as collective asset and
liability managers for their members. In this role, the cooperatives,
in effect, face the financial markets as intermediaries for their
members. These cooperatives sometimes enter into swaps with members and
with non-member counterparties, typically SDs or other financial
entities, to hedge the risks associated with the swaps or loans they
execute with their members, or to hedge risks associated with their
wholesale borrowing activities, the proceeds of which are used to fund
member loans. If these financial entity cooperatives have total assets
in excess of $10 billion, then the cooperatives do not qualify for the
small financial institution exemption and thus cannot elect the end-
user exception.
Some cooperatives with more than $10 billion in total assets have
members that are non-financial entities, small financial institutions,
or other cooperatives whose members consist of such entities.\15\ For
example, there are four Farm Credit System (``FCS'') banks chartered
under Federal law, each of which has total assets in excess of $10
billion.\16\ The FCS banks are
[[Page 52288]]
cooperatives primarily owned by their cooperative associations.\17\ The
FCS banks are regulated and prudentially supervised by the Farm Credit
Administration (``FCA''), an independent agency of the Federal
government.\18\ The Farm Credit Act authorizes the banks ``to make
loans and commitments to eligible cooperative associations.'' \19\ The
FCS association members are, in turn, cooperatives authorized to make
loans to farmers and ranchers, rural residents, and persons furnishing
farm-related services.\20\ In effect, FCS bank cooperatives primarily
make loans to FCS association cooperatives, which lend to farmers and
ranchers, rural residents, and persons furnishing farm-related
services, and these borrowers are member-owners of the FCS
associations, which are member-owners of the FCS banks. In addition to
the example of the FCS banks, other cooperatives formed under federal
and state laws also have a similar entity structure in that they are
owned and governed by their members and they exist to serve those
members.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\15\ See, e.g., comments received on the end-user exception NPRM
from FCC, CFC, AEC, ALM, and GEC.
\16\ See FCA, 2011 Annual Report on the Farm Credit System, at
11, available at https://www.fca.gov/Download/AnnualReports/2011AnnualReport.pdf.
\17\ See 12 U.S.C. 2124(c) (providing that ``[v]oting stock may
be issued or transferred to and held only by . . . cooperative
associations eligible to borrow from the banks.'').
\18\ See id. at 2241.
\19\ Id. at 2128(a).
\20\ See id. at 2075.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The cooperative exemption, in effect, provides the end-user
exception created in section 2(h)(7) of the CEA to financial entity
cooperatives when acting in the interests of their members and in
connection with loans to members. The exemption benefits the members
that qualify for the end-user exception (or members that are
cooperatives whose own members qualify for the end-user exception)
because they own and control the cooperatives, which exist for the
mutual benefit of its members. As described in greater detail
below,\21\ in the laws that establish financial cooperatives as legal
entities distinct from other business structures, Congress and state
legislatures made a policy determination to facilitate the formation of
cooperatives in order to provide the cooperative members with the
unique benefits of accessing markets on a cooperative basis. In this
way, financial cooperatives were created to serve as an alternative
source of capital for their members. Some of the laws establishing
cooperatives acknowledge that cooperatives will compete with other
market participants and may have certain benefits or advantages that
are acceptable for promoting the benefits that members achieve through
their cooperatives.\22\ Because the cooperatives are established to
serve their members and the net earnings they generate through their
activities are returned to those members, the benefits of the
cooperative exemption ultimately inure to the members of the
cooperative. In the context of required clearing and the end-user
exception, the cooperative exemption furthers the purpose for which
financial cooperatives were established, i.e., to act for the mutual
benefit of their members.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\21\ See section IV.
\22\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
III. Comments on the Proposed Cooperative Exemption Rule
A. Introduction
In proposing an exemption for certain swaps entered into by certain
cooperatives that are financial entities, the Commission acknowledged
in the NPRM that central clearing of swaps is a primary focus of Title
VII of the Dodd-Frank Act. Central clearing mitigates financial system
risks that could result from swaps and any exemption from central
clearing should be narrowly drawn to minimize the impact on the risk
mitigation benefits of clearing and should also be in line with the
end-user exception requirements of section 2(h)(7) of the CEA.
Accordingly, the Commission sought to narrowly tailor the cooperative
exemption by limiting the types of entities that could elect the
cooperative exemption and the types of swaps for which the exemption
could be elected.
The Commission received a number of comment letters both supporting
and opposing the proposed cooperative exemption. Fourteen rural
electric cooperatives (``Rural Electric Cooperatives'') \23\ and their
trade association, the National Rural Electric Cooperative Association
(``NRECA'') submitted substantially similar comment letters supporting
the rulemaking. The FCC, the National Rural Utilities Cooperative
Finance Corporation (``CFC''),\24\ the Credit Union National
Association (``CUNA''), the American Farm Bureau Federation (``AFBF''),
Chris Barnard (``Mr. Barnard''), and the National Council of Farmer
Cooperatives (``NCFC'') similarly supported the proposed cooperative
exemption. Eleven of the twelve Federal Home Loan Banks (``FHL Banks'')
submitted a comment letter supporting the concept of a cooperative
exemption generally, but requested certain changes to the rule as
described below.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\23\ See Allegheny Electric Cooperative, Inc., Coast Electric
Power Association, Choptank Electric Cooperative, Claiborne Electric
Cooperative, Inc., Deaf Smith Electric Cooperative Inc., Dixie
Electric Cooperative, First Electric Cooperative Inc., Garkane
Energy, Hoosier Energy Rural Electric Cooperative, Inc., Mountain
View Electric Association, Inc., Pioneer Rural Electric Cooperative,
Inc., Sullivan County Rural Electric Cooperative, Inc., Sumter
Electric Cooperative, Inc., and Sunflower Electric Power
Corporation.
\24\ The comment letter from the CFC incorporates, as an
attachment, the signatures of approximately 500 individuals
associated with nonprofit rural electric cooperatives supporting the
cooperative exemption.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The American Bankers Association (``ABA''), Lake City Bank, and the
Independent Community Bankers of America (``ICBA'') submitted comments
opposing the cooperative exemption on several grounds. All three
opposed the rule on the grounds that it provides cooperatives with
advantages at the expense of certain banks. The ABA and ICBA generally
objected to the rule because they believe the reasoning behind the
proposed rule was faulty and that the rule making did not comply with
the requirements of section 4(c) of the CEA and the Administrative
Procedure Act (``APA''). They also commented on the efficacy of the
cost-benefit analysis in the NPRM.
The following discussion first addresses comments on each paragraph
of the proposed rule followed by a discussion of the comments
addressing compliance of the proposed rule with the legal parameters
applicable to the rulemaking under section 4(c) of the CEA.
B. Regulation 39.6(f)(1) (now Sec. 50.51(a)): Definition of Exempt
Cooperative
The end-user exception is generally available to entities,
including cooperatives, that are not ``financial entities,'' as defined
in section 2(h)(7)(C)(i) of the CEA, and entities that would be
financial entities, including cooperatives, but for the fact that they
meet the requirements of the small financial institution exemption in
Sec. 50.50(d). The proposed cooperative exemption would add an
exemption from required clearing for cooperatives that do not fall into
these two categories if they meet the definition of ``exempt
cooperative.'' Proposed Sec. 39.6(f)(1) (now Sec. 50.51(a)) defines
``exempt cooperative'' to mean a cooperative that is a ``financial
entity'' solely as defined in section 2(h)(7)(C)(i)(VIII) of the CEA
for which each member of the cooperative is either (1) a non-financial
entity, (2) a financial institution to which the small financial
institution exemption applies, or (3) itself a cooperative each of
whose members fall into either of the first two categories.
The Commission received a number of comment letters in support of
the Commission's rationale provided in the
[[Page 52289]]
NPRM for the proposed definition of exempt cooperative. The Rural
Electric Cooperatives and NRECA agreed with the Commission's proposed
definition of ``exempt cooperative'' and the Commission's reasons for
establishing the exemption. The Rural Electric Cooperatives commented
that the exempt cooperative definition is appropriate because members
of exempt cooperatives would be eligible for the end-user exception if
entering into swaps on their own. In their view, effectively extending
the end-user exception available to the members of an exempt
cooperative to the exempt cooperative itself is appropriate because the
members act in the financial markets through the cooperatives that they
own.
The FCC, the CFC, CUNA, Mr. Barnard, and the NCFC similarly
supported the Commission's definition of exempt cooperative. Like the
Rural Electric Cooperatives, the FCC suggested that the ``unique
structure of cooperatives and their relationship to their member-
owners'' warrants the cooperative exemption. The CFC and Mr. Barnard
supported the ``pass-through concept'' embodied in the cooperative
exemption. The FHL Banks commented that the unique ownership structure
of cooperatives and the fact that cooperatives act on behalf of
``members that are non-financial institutions or small financial
institutions'' justify the Commission issuing the cooperative
exemption.
The ABA and the ICBA submitted comments opposing the definition of
exempt cooperative because they believe there is no policy
justification for the exemption and that the Commission's reasons for
the exemption are not analytically appropriate. They commented that
cooperatives do not play a unique role and are not themselves unique.
The ABA suggested the Commission ignored the ``fact that banks perform
the same functions for customers that cooperatives perform for their
members.'' Similarly, the ICBA commented that the Commission has not
described how exempt cooperatives differ from commercial banks.
According to ICBA, ``community banks play the same role on behalf of
their customers'' that cooperatives play when facing the larger
financial markets on behalf of their members. Both the ABA and the ICBA
also noted that banks enter into swaps to hedge risks. The ABA noted
that almost one-third of all the loans made by the FCS did not involve
individual farmers or ranchers.
According to the ICBA, smaller ``community'' banks should be given
the ``same exemption as any financial cooperative of the same or larger
size.'' The ICBA and the ABA requested that ``smaller'' banks, with
assets above the $10 billion threshold in the end-user exception, be
exempted from mandatory clearing along with cooperatives.
In response, the Commission does not disagree with these comments
to the extent that banks often provide the same services to their
customers that exempt cooperatives provide to their members. However,
the nature of the services provided by cooperatives to their members is
not the rationale for the cooperative exemption. The Commission's
rationale is based in large part on the relationship between a
cooperative and its members, which is different from the relationship
between banks and their customers. The cooperative exemption in effect
provides the end-user exception created in section 2(h)(7) of the CEA
to entities whose members themselves qualify for the end-user
exception, but would otherwise not be able to realize the full effects
of the exception when those members act in the financial markets
through their member-owned exempt cooperatives that do not qualify for
the small financial institution exemption. The rule benefits the
members who qualify for the end-user exception through the cooperatives
that they own and control and exist for their mutual benefit. Because
the cooperatives are established to serve their members and the net
earnings they generate through their activities are returned to those
members, the benefits of the cooperative exemption ultimately inure to
the members of the cooperative.
The Commission notes that the definition of ``exempt cooperative''
is narrowly tailored so that only a cooperative for which each of its
members individually, or if it has members that are cooperatives, each
of the members of those cooperatives individually, would qualify for
the end-user exception would qualify for the cooperative exemption.
Furthermore, Sec. 39.6(f)(2) (now Sec. 50.51(b)) provides that the
exemption is only available for swaps executed in connection with
originating member loans and swaps that hedge or mitigate risk related
to loans to members or arising from certain swaps with members. As
such, under the final rule, an exempt cooperative shall not elect the
exemption for swaps related to non-member activity of the cooperative.
Exempt cooperatives are distinct from banks not because of the
services they offer, but because they exist to serve their members'
interests and act as intermediaries for their members in the
marketplace. The member-owners generally are the customers of the
cooperatives and the Commission drafted the proposed rule to be
available only to the extent the cooperative exemption is used in
connection with member-related activities. Cooperatives are owned by
their members and as such, their governing bodies generally consist of
members. Their net earnings are returned to their members either
through rebates or distributions, often referred to as ``patronage,''
or are retained by the cooperatives as capital to be used to provide
services to members. For example, the FCC noted in its comments that
FCS cooperatives were established by federal law to operate for the
benefit of farmer-owners.\25\ The FCC further noted that by law, each
cooperative association in the FCS has a board of directors comprised
of voting members of the association, and as required by law, at least
one ``outside'' director.\26\ Furthermore, voting stock may only be
held by farmers, ranchers, producers of aquatic products, and
cooperative associations eligible to borrow from FCS institutions.\27\
Each owner of association voting stock is entitled to one vote in the
affairs of the association, regardless of the amount of the stock
held.\28\ FCS additionally commented that each year FCS cooperatives
pay patronage to their members, both in cash and allocated equity.\29\
Furthermore, unlike for-profit entities that generally pay out
dividends based on the amount of stock purchased by each investor, as
discussed in greater detail below, cooperatives generally pay out or
allocate earnings to the member-owners based on the amount of business
[[Page 52290]]
undertaken by each member with the cooperative.\30\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\25\ The FCC cited Section 1.1(a) of the Farm Credit Act (12
U.S.C. 2001) (``farmer-owned cooperative Farm Credit System'') and
Section 1.1(b) thereof (``It is the objective of this chapter to
continue to encourage farmer- and rancher-borrowers participation in
the management, control, and ownership of a permanent system of
credit for agriculture which will be responsive to the credit needs
of all types of agricultural producers having a basis for credit,
and to modernize and improve the authorizations and means for
furnishing such credit and credit for housing in rural areas made
available through the institutions constituting the Farm Credit
System as herein provided.'').
\26\ 12 U.S.C. 2072.
\27\ 12 U.S.C. 2154a(c)(1)(D)(i).
\28\ 12 CFR 611.350.
\29\ For example, in 2011, FCS institutions distributed about
$903 million in cash patronage and $243 million in stock patronage
to the approximately 489,000 system shareholders. Farm Credit
Admin., 2011 Annual Report on the Farm Credit System, 18 (2011);
Press Release, Fed. Farm Credit Banks Funding Corp., Farm Credit
System Reports Net Income of $3.940 Billion for 2011, 5 (Feb. 17,
2012), available at https://www.farmcreditfunding.com/farmcredit/serve/public/pressre/finin/report.pdf?assetId=198426.
\30\ See 18 a.m. Jur. 2d Cooperative Associations Sec. 19
(2012) (``Ordinarily, the profits of a cooperative association are
distributed to its members in the form of patronage refunds or
dividends in amounts determined by the use made of the association
facilities by the patrons, and statutes frequently so provide.'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
On the other hand, banks generally are for-profit, publicly or
privately held corporations whose investor-owners are not required to
be the users of the bank's services, and often are not. The governing
bodies of banks, like other for-profit entities, are typically elected
by the shareholders whose voting power is determined by the amount of
common stock each investor owns. A board of directors of a corporation
has a legal duty to the corporation and the shareholders and,
accordingly, must consider shareholder value in its actions.\31\ As
such, unlike the member-focused purposes of exempt cooperatives, a
primary purpose of banks is to generate value for their owners, who
generally are not their customers. The mission of a cooperative is to
act in the interests of its members, while the goal of a for-profit
business, whatever its size, is to benefit the owners of that business,
which are not necessarily its customers. Unlike a cooperative, which is
an extension of its members as a business matter, a bank is not an
extension of its customers. Accordingly, the Commission believes the
rationale for extending the end-user exception to cooperatives does not
apply to banks in the same way.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\31\ See, e.g., 18B Am. Jur. 2d Corporations 1460 (2012).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The ICBA further questioned whether ``members'' are any different
from ``customers,'' because, in the case of the FCS, borrowers can be
considered owners or members even if they do not put their own capital
into the organization. For example, according to the ICBA, an FCS
borrower can become a member by paying an additional $1,000 on a loan
or one percent of the loan value, whichever is less.
The FCC commented that the Farm Credit Act and related regulations
prescribe minimum stock purchase requirements for FCS borrowers and
also require that FCS institutions meet minimum capital standards well
in excess of the amount of purchased stock, citing 12 U.S.C. 2151. The
FCC noted that as of December 31, 2011, combined FCS association
capital was over $24 billion dollars, or 19% of outstanding loans.
Furthermore, the FCS noted that ``[v]irtually all that capital is the
result of income earned and retained.''
The Commission believes that the comments of the ICBA and FCC on
this issue further demonstrate the uniqueness of the member-owner
relationship between exempt cooperatives and their members and how the
cooperatives are, in effect, extensions of their members acting in the
interests of their members in a way that is not the case for the
relationship between other types of financial institutions and their
customers. The earnings retained by FCS cooperatives would otherwise be
paid out to members pro rata based on the amount of borrowing from the
cooperatives. As such, a cooperative member has a vested, pro rata
interest in its cooperative based on the amount of business the member
does with the cooperative. While a for-profit entity such as a bank
also may retain capital, the capital, if paid out to the owners, would
be paid to the equity investors, not the customers of the entity and
not based on the amount of business the customers do with the entity.
The ICBA and the ABA further commented that some of the entities
that the cooperatives are ``standing in the marketplace on behalf of''
are sophisticated entities and are capable of entering into the swap
marketplace on their own and do not need a cooperative to face the
market. The ICBA also commented that all of the component entities of
cooperatives would have ``no trouble arranging financing from private
sector sources.''
The Commission did not assert in the NPRM that the members of
cooperatives could only access financial markets through the
cooperatives or that sole access through cooperatives was a reason for
the proposed rule. Rather, the Commission recognized that certain
entities for which the end-user exception is available have
traditionally accessed the markets through financial cooperatives that
they own and which exist for their benefit. For example, this
relationship is well established and is codified into the federal law
that created the FCS.\32\ If the cooperative exemption were not adopted
by the Commission, these entities would not be able to both continue to
use their cooperatives and receive the full benefit of the end-user
exception created in the Dodd-Frank Act.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\32\ ``It is declared to be the policy of the Congress . . .
that the farmer-owned cooperative [FCS] be designed to accomplish
the objective of improving the income and well-being of American
farmers and ranchers by furnishing sound, adequate, and constructive
credit and closely related services to them, their cooperatives, and
to selected farm-related businesses necessary for efficient farm
operations.'' 12 U.S.C. 2001(a).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The ICBA questioned the Commission's statement in the preamble to
the proposed cooperative exemption that ``cooperatives exist to serve
their member-owners and do not act for their own profit.'' The ICBA
commented that the FCS, credit unions and other cooperatives ``pay
their executives millions of dollars each year.''
The ICBA, Lake City Bank, and ABA also noted that the FCS and
credit unions and other cooperatives that would be able to use the
cooperative exemption already enjoy a number of significant advantages,
such as low-cost funding, tax exemptions, and, in some cases,
government sponsored enterprise (``GSE'') status. They expressed
concern that providing credit unions, FCS cooperatives, and other
cooperatives with an exemption from mandatory clearing would
``exacerbate their competitive advantage over banks.'' Furthermore, the
ICBA stated that ``FCS lenders have in recent years positioned
themselves to act almost identically to banks through deposit taking
arrangements, credit card offerings, check writing capabilities and
outright illegitimate activities granted by their permissive
regulator.''
The Commission is not responsible for the creation, administration,
or implementation of those legal characteristics of cooperatives
referred to in the comments as being ``competitive advantages.'' These
characteristics, by and large, flow from policies enacted by Congress
or state legislatures. Further, the Commission is not the regulator
responsible for the laws and regulations referred to by commenters that
govern cooperatives. The Commission has determined without regard to
such other asserted benefits for cooperatives, to offer an elective
clearing exemption to entities qualifying as exempt cooperatives to
extend the full benefits of the end-user exception established in the
Dodd-Frank Act to entities that would qualify for that exception, but
which choose to act through their cooperatives in the financial
marketplace.\33\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\33\ For a discussion of the related ``fair competition''
provision in section 4(c), see section IV herein.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Comments regarding the compensation of executives are outside the
scope of this rulemaking. The rationale for the cooperative exemption
is based on the member-owner structure of cooperatives, not on how much
executives are paid or whether that pay is fair. The Commission defers
to the regulators who enforce those regulations
[[Page 52291]]
for issues related to executive compensation.
With respect to swaps, the ICBA noted that cooperatives and
community banks both enter into swaps to hedge the interest rate risk
of loans to their customers or members. The ICBA suggested that swaps
hedging the underlying risks of loans to customers pose the same lower
risk to the financial system that the FCC claims regarding swaps
hedging the risks of loans to its cooperative members.
The Commission notes that it is not relying on the assertion by the
FCC that swaps related to hedging loans to cooperative members may be
less risky than other types of swaps that financial entities may
undertake as a primary reason for distinguishing exempt cooperatives
from other types of lending entities.\34\ As explained in the NPRM, the
potential lower risk of such swaps is, however, one of the reasons why
the Commission is restricting the cooperative exemption to swaps
related to member loans.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\34\ The Commission believes, however, that because exempt
cooperatives serve their members and are controlled by their
members, it can be expected that cooperatives will focus their swap
activity on member loan-related activities.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The National Association of Federal Credit Unions requested that
the Commission specify that the cooperative exemption applies to ``all
credit unions.'' The Commission clarifies that the exemption applies to
all cooperatives, including credit unions that meet the definition of
``exempt cooperative'' in the final rule. The Commission does not have
enough information to determine whether ``all credit unions'' are
eligible for the exemption. Whether any particular credit union meets
the definition of an exempt cooperative will depend on the relevant
facts and circumstances for that credit union.
The FHL Banks stated that they would not qualify as exempt
cooperatives because each FHL Bank has one or more members that are
financial institutions that do not qualify for the small financial
institution exemption. The FHL Banks commented that the cooperative
exemption, as proposed, would ``unfairly and arbitrarily'' penalize
members of a cooperative that would qualify as small financial
institutions under the end-user exception if the cooperative also has
one or more large financial institutions as members. The FHL Banks
stated that this would result in the inconsistent treatment of two
similarly situated entities. The FHL Banks also point to the joint
final rule on the definition of the term ``swap dealer,'' where the
Securities and Exchange Commission along with the Commission excluded
all swaps between a cooperative and its members from the analysis of
whether that cooperative is an SD. This regulatory treatment, according
to the FHL Banks, would be ``consistent'' with the Commission allowing
the FHL Banks to elect the cooperative exemption in certain
circumstances.
The FHL Banks requested that the Commission remove the limitation
that bars a cooperative from being an ``exempt cooperative'' if it has
one or more members that are financial entities that are not themselves
cooperatives with members that qualify for the end-user exception.
Instead, the FHL Banks suggested that the Commission allow cooperatives
to enter into swaps that hedge or mitigate commercial risk related to
loans to ``qualified members'' or arising from swaps entered into with
``qualified members'' that are eligible for the end-user exception. The
FHL Banks proposed the term ``qualified member'' to mean a member of an
exempt cooperative that is (1) not a financial entity, (2) a financial
entity that is exempt from the definition of financial entity under the
small financial institution exemption in Sec. 50.50(d), or (3) a
cooperative, each member of which is not a financial entity or is
exempt from mandatory clearing because it qualifies for the small
financial institution exemption. The FHL Banks commented that their
proposed approach is consistent with the Dodd-Frank Act's objective of
mandating that swaps entered into in connection with or for large
financial institutions be cleared, without penalizing small financial
institutions. According to the FHL Banks, their proposed revisions to
the cooperative exemption would allow FHL Banks to qualify as an
``exempt cooperative,'' in appropriate situations. The FHL Banks also
stated that this revised cooperative exemption would apply to less than
10% of the outstanding notional amount of the FHL Banks' swaps. The
ICBA, like the FHL Banks, suggested that the Commission revise the
definition of exempt cooperative to not exclude the FHL Banks ``to the
extent that they engage in swaps for the benefit of their members who
individually qualify as small financial institutions.''
In response to the FHL Banks' and the ICBA's comments regarding
cooperatives that are ineligible for the cooperative exemption because
they have one or more financial entity members, the Commission declines
to extend the exemption beyond the parameters as proposed. The
Commission disagrees with the FHL Banks' assertion that the cooperative
exemption is arbitrary or unfair to financial institutions that qualify
for the small financial institution exemption. Under Sec.
39.6(f)(1)(iii)(A) (now Sec. 50.51(a)(3)(i)) of the proposed rule,
small financial institutions that meet the definition thereof in Sec.
50.50(d) can be members of exempt cooperatives. These members can
include banks, savings associations, FCS institutions, or credit
unions, so long as each of them qualifies as a small financial
institution under Sec. 50.50(d) (i.e. the institution has total assets
of $10 billion or less). They would be treated in the same way as all
other entities that may qualify for the end-user exception, and
therefore can be members of exempt cooperatives as defined.
Furthermore, as the Commission acknowledged above and in the NPRM,
it is concerned that exemptions from the clearing requirement could
detract from the systemic risk reducing benefits of clearing. This is
particularly a concern if the exemption could be elected for swaps that
relate to risks of entities that Congress clearly intended to be
subject to the clearing requirement--financial entities as defined in
section 2(h)(7)(C) of the CEA that are not expressly exempted from that
definition. As such, the Commission narrowed the cooperative exemption
to apply solely to a cooperative whose members (or if it has members
that are cooperatives, the members of those cooperatives) could
themselves elect the end-user exception.
The importance of a narrow cooperative exemption is apparent when
considering the possible effect of broadening the exemption in the
manner requested by the FHL Banks and ICBA. A fundamental
characteristic of cooperatives is that they distribute or allocate the
patronage earnings of the cooperative, i.e., the excess of a
cooperative's revenues over its costs arising from transactions done
with or for its members,\35\ to each member based on the amount of
patronage by the member, i.e., proportionally based on the amount of
business each member does with the cooperative.\36\ Accordingly, even
if a cooperative with financial entity members only elected
[[Page 52292]]
the cooperative exemption for swaps related to loans to members that
qualify for the end-user exception, a portion of the financial benefits
from those swaps in the form of higher net income may shift from the
qualifying small members to the larger members as part of the full
member pro rata patronage distribution or allocation. Furthermore, the
risks of such swaps because they are non-cleared could also negatively
impact the large financial institution members to the extent that the
net income of the cooperative is negatively impacted.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\35\ See FASB ASC 905-10-05.
\36\ The distribution or allocation of patronage earnings to the
members based on the amount of business they do with the cooperative
is a guiding principle of cooperatives and is a necessary element
for a cooperative to claim a deduction for taxation purposes under
federal law. See Donald A. Frederick, Income Tax Treatment of
Cooperatives: Background, Cooperative Information Report 44, Part 1,
2005 Ed. (April 2005) at 50, citing, Puget Sound Plywood, Inc. v.
Commissioner, 44 T.C. 305, 308 (1965).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
As an example, consider the relative amounts of lending by the FHL
Banks to those of their largest members that do not qualify for the
end-user exception as compared to the FHL Banks' lending to their other
members. The 12 FHL Banks had 7,774 members as of the end of 2011.\37\
Each of the 12 FHL Banks reported the amount of lending business they
did with their five largest members in the 2011 Combined Financial
Report for the FHL Banks. In 2011, $222.6 billion of the $403.3 billion
lent by the FHL Banks to their members was lent to the largest five
members of each of the 12 FHL Banks.\38\ Of those 60 large members,
approximately 49 had total assets in excess of $10 billion.\39\ The
amount loaned to those 49 members was about $212.7 billion, or 53% of
the dollar amount lent by the FHL Banks. Furthermore, those 49 members
do not include all members of the FHL Banks with assets greater than
$10 billion. Accordingly, the Commission estimates the percentage of
lending by the FHL Banks to members that cannot qualify for the end-
user exception was higher than 53% of total lending in 2011.\40\ If the
FHL Banks were able to use the cooperative exemption, under the
cooperative structure in which patronage benefits are allocated pro
rata based on the amount of business each member does with the
cooperative, a significant portion of the benefits and risks from the
election of the exemption could spread to the large financial entity
members. This would also be the case even if the exemption were only
available to swaps related to small financial institutions because the
distribution of patronage to the members is based to a large degree on
the amount of borrowing by each member.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\37\ FHL Banks, Combined Financial Report for the Year Ended
December 31, 2011 (issued March 29, 2012) at 43, available at https://www.fhlb-of.com/ofweb_userWeb/resources/11yrend.pdf.
\38\ Id. at 44-45. The Commission arrived at the $222.6 billion
amount by adding together the loan values of the 60 individual
members listed in the Combined Financial Report of the FHL Banks.
\39\ The Commission estimated this number by reviewing
publically available information related to the assets of each of
the 60 members, such as members' annual 10-K financial reports filed
with the SEC (available on the SEC's Web site and posted on the
members' Web sites), other annual financial reports and information,
such as press releases posted on members' Web sites, and reports
published by the Federal Reserve and Federal Deposit Insurance
Corporation. As an example, the Commission reviewed the Federal
Reserve's Statistical Release for Large Banks, which provided
information regarding the total assets held by 27 of the 60 members.
See Federal Reserve, Statistical Release for Large Banks, available
at https://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/lbr/current/default.htm.
\40\ The FHL Banks Combined Financial Report for the Year Ended
December 31, 2011, does not break down lending amount for every
member. The 49 members used in the Commission's calculations do not
include all members of the FHL Banks with assets greater than $10
billion. Accordingly, while the total percentage of lending to
financial entities with total assets greater than $10 billion cannot
be calculated based on the information available in the financial
report, it is likely significantly higher than the 53% calculated
for the 49 members with over $10 billion in total assets for which
lending information is available.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Similarly, the Commission is concerned that allowing cooperatives
with members that do not qualify for the end-user exception to elect
the cooperative exemption could open up avenues for abuse of the
exemption and evasion of clearing. For example, larger financial
entities could form cooperatives capitalized by the large financial
entities, but which also include small affiliates or trading partners
of the larger financial entities that would qualify as small financial
institutions. They could then use these cooperatives to shift their
borrowing and swap needs between the large and small entities to be
able to take advantage of the cooperative exception in ways that
benefit the larger institutions. The Commission considers these risks
of abuse of the exemption and evasion of the clearing requirement
warrant limiting the definition of exempt cooperative as written. The
Commission notes that small financial institutions can elect the end-
user exception themselves.
The ICBA noted that the Dodd-Frank Act's requirement that the
Commission consider exempting small financial institutions is not
necessarily limited to institutions with less than $10 billion in total
assets. The ICBA commented that there are 36 ``community banks'' \41\
with assets over $10 billion, and within the category of ``community
banks,'' the asset sizes of those banks range from $10.5 billion to $50
billion. The ICBA suggested that the asset size test in the end-user
exception be increased up to $50 billion or that community banks be
given a ``ride along'' provision so that community banks that do not
qualify for the end-user exception could elect the same exemption as
cooperatives.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\41\ The ICBA did not specifically define the term ``community
banks'' other than by reference to the $50 billion maximum asset
level.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
With these comments, the ICBA is effectively asking the Commission
to reopen and revise the end-user exception rule as applied to
financial institutions generally. The Commission set forth the reasons
for the $10 billion total asset limit for small financial institutions
in the end-user exception rulemaking and believes that those reasons
remain appropriate. This rulemaking addresses the specific issue of
whether an exemption from clearing should be granted to certain
cooperatives--including the issue of whether there are relevant
differences between the covered cooperatives and private banks--and is
not intended as a vehicle for reopening the end-user exception
regulations.
C. Regulation 39.6(f)(2) (now Sec. 50.51(b)): Swaps to Which the
Cooperative Exemption Applies
Proposed Sec. 39.6(f)(2) (now 50.51(b)) limits application of the
cooperative exemption to swaps entered into with members of the exempt
cooperative in connection with originating loans \42\ for members or
swaps entered into by exempt cooperatives that hedge or mitigate risks
related to loans to members or arising from member loan-related swaps.
This provision assures that the cooperative exemption is used only for
swaps related to member lending activities. Since the definition of an
exempt cooperative requires that all members be entities who can elect
the end-user exception or cooperatives all of whose members can, this
condition assures that the exemption will benefit entities who could
themselves elect the end-user exception and can be used for swaps that
hedge or mitigate risk in connection with member loans and swaps as
would be required by section 2(h)(7)(A)(ii) of the CEA.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\42\ The phrase ``in connection with originating a loan'' is
similarly used in the definition of swap dealer in Sec. 1.3(ggg) of
the Commission's Regulations. See 77 FR 30596, 30744 (May 23, 2012).
That meaning is incorporated in the final rule.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The primary rationale for the cooperative exemption is based on the
unique relationship between cooperatives and their member-owners.
Expanding this exemption to include swaps related to non-member
activities would extend the exemption beyond its intended purpose.
Furthermore, allowing cooperatives to enter into non-cleared swaps with
non-member borrowers, or swaps that serve purposes other than hedging
member loans or
[[Page 52293]]
swaps, would give the cooperatives, which are large financial entities,
an exception from regulatory requirements that would not be provided to
other market participants engaging in such similar business with
respect to non-members that is not justified by their cooperative
structure or the provisions of the Dodd-Frank Act.
The CFC commented that it agrees with the types of swaps eligible
for the cooperative exemption described by the Commission in the
preamble of the NPRM. The CFC stated that the use of the phrase
``related to'' in the rule text is consistent with the ``pass-through
concept'' that underlies the cooperative exemption. The FCC suggested
that the Commission provide additional clarity on the ``related to''
standard. The FCC commented that the ``related to'' standard should be
broad enough to cover swaps that hedge or mitigate risk related to
``interest rate, liquidity, and balance sheet risks'' associated with a
cooperative's lending business. The FCC pointed to the statement in the
preamble to the proposed rule that explained that the ``related to''
test involves hedging or mitigating risks ``associated with'' member
loans. The FCC supported this interpretation. The FCC requested that
the Commission clarify that certain types of transactions would be
covered by the cooperative exemption. Specifically, the FCC suggested
that the following swaps should be covered by the cooperative
exemption: (1) Swaps managing interest rate, liquidity, and balance
sheet risk, (2) swaps qualifying as GAAP hedges of bonds and floating
rate notes, and (3) swaps hedging FCS banks' liquidity reserves that
are required by the FCA.
The AFBF also requested that the Commission clarify that swaps
mitigating or hedging balance sheet, interest rate, and liquidity risks
associated with their cooperative lending business are eligible for the
cooperative exemption.
The Commission's rationale for the cooperative exemption is based
on the unique relationship between a cooperative and its members. The
primary purpose for the cooperative exemption is to, in effect, provide
the full benefits of the end-user exception created in section 2(h)(7)
of the CEA to entities that qualify for the end-user exception, but
otherwise do not receive the full benefits of the exception if they use
their cooperatives as their intermediary in the markets as they have
traditionally done. Thus, the Commission will interpret this exemption
to ensure that the exemption is only used for swaps that are undertaken
to directly further the interests of the members who are themselves
eligible for the end-user exception. Accordingly, the Commission
declines to expand the types of transactions eligible for the exemption
beyond those swaps that are entered into in connection with originating
a loan or loans for a member, or swaps that hedge or mitigate
commercial risk related to loans with members, or hedge or mitigate the
commercial risk associated with a swap between an exempt cooperative
and its members in connection with originating loans to members.
With respect to the comments of the AFBF and the FCC regarding
swaps that hedge balance sheet, interest rate, and liquidity risks
associated with their cooperative lending business, the Commission
reiterates that only those swaps relating to member loans are eligible
for the exemption, not swaps related to a cooperative's entire lending
business to the extent that lending business includes loans to non-
members. Accordingly, the exemption may be used for swaps that hedge
balance sheet, interest rate, and liquidity risks, but only limited to
the extent those risks are related to loans made by the cooperative to
its members. The Commission is concerned that without this limitation,
cooperatives could use this exemption for risks related to non-member-
based activities, which would be inconsistent with the general
rationale for the exemption and could result in a competitive benefit
to eligible cooperatives that is also inconsistent with the
Commission's rationale for the exemption.
As the text of Sec. 39.6(f)(2)(i) (now Sec. 50.51(b)(1))
provides, the phrase ``swap is entered into with a member of the exempt
cooperative in connection with originating a loan or loans for the
member'' should be read consistent with 17 CFR 1.3(ggg)(5). Among other
things, 17 CFR 1.3(ggg)(5) provides that an acceptable swap includes a
swap with members for which the rate, asset, liability or other
notional item underlying such swap is, or is directly related to, a
financial term of such loan, which includes, without limitation, the
loan's duration, rate of interest, the currency or currencies in which
it is made and its principal amount; or the swap is required, as a
condition of the loan under the exempt cooperative's loan underwriting
criteria, to be in place in order to hedge price risks incidental to
the borrower's business and arising from potential changes in the price
of a commodity (other than an excluded commodity).
Section 39.6(f)(2)(ii) (now Sec. 50.51(b)(2)) also includes in the
cooperative exemption swaps that hedge or mitigate risk related to
loans to members or arising from a swap or swaps with members entered
into pursuant to Sec. 39.6(f)(2)(i) (now Sec. 50.51(b)(1)). This
provision includes swaps that the exempt cooperatives may enter into
with non-members to hedge or mitigate the risks incurred by the
cooperatives related to their member lending activities. Such swaps can
include swaps entered into with non-member parties (e.g., SDs) to hedge
or mitigate risks such as interest rate risk related to funding loans
to fund member loans, or liquidity or balance sheet risks, so long as
those liquidity and balance sheet risks arise from activities related
to member loans.
As discussed above in this section, the risks must be related to
member loans only. For example, the Commission understands that
cooperatives sometimes issue bonds or enter into wholesale funding
transactions to fund member and non-member loans. The cooperative
exemption would permit an exemption for swaps, such as interest rate
swaps or interest rate caps, used to hedge those funding transactions,
but only to the extent that the interest rate swaps or interest rate
caps relate to member-associated loans. Only swaps hedging or
mitigating risk arising from the portion of the bonds or wholesale
funding proceeds that is related to, or is expected to be related to,
direct loans to members are eligible for the exemption. Practically
speaking, this means that for a cooperative borrowing on a wholesale
basis for both member and non-member-associated loans, the aggregate
notional amount of any non-cleared swaps hedging the wholesale funding
loans must not exceed the aggregate principal value of the wholesale
funding loans less the aggregate principal amount lent or expected to
be lent to non-members. Cooperatives would need to adjust that
aggregate notional amount by termination or other means as soon as
practicable if that aggregate amount is exceeded during the life of any
such swaps.
As another example, eligible cooperatives may want to hedge
interest rate risk associated with a portfolio of loans to multiple
borrowers with one or more swaps. If the loan portfolio being hedged
consists solely of loans to members, then the cooperative exemption
would be available for those hedging swaps if the requirements of Sec.
39.6(f) (now Sec. 50.51) are met. However, if the cooperative has non-
member loans in the loan portfolio being hedged, then the swap may be
hedging risk that is not related to
[[Page 52294]]
member loans and, if so, the exemption would not be available for that
swap. In order to be able to elect the exemption for swaps that hedge a
portfolio of member loans and non-member loans, the aggregate notional
amount of any such swaps must not exceed the aggregate principal amount
of the member loans in the portfolio. Cooperatives would need to adjust
that notional amount by termination or other means, such as clearing
certain swaps, as soon as practicable if that amount is exceeded during
the life of any such swap. The same limitation applies to balance sheet
risks. The exemption may be elected for swaps hedging balance sheet
risks only to the extent they arise from member loan related activity.
For example, balance sheet risks could be hedged with swaps for which
the cooperative exemption may be available to the extent that the
aggregate notional amount of such swaps does not exceed the aggregate
principal amount of member loans.
With respect to FCC's comments relating to ``liquidity reserves''
required by the FCA, the Commission believes the same general approach
described above should apply. That is, swaps hedging risks related to
liquidity reserves may be eligible for the exemption only to the extent
that such reserves being hedged are related to member loans. For
example, if a cooperative makes loans to both members and non-members
and hedges risks related to liquidity reserves for the combined loan
portfolio, the cooperative would be permitted to elect the exemption
for the hedging swaps to the extent that the aggregate notional amount
of the swaps does not exceed an amount equal to the total liquidity
reserves multiplied by the proportion of the member loans principal
amount to the total principal amount of member loans and non-member
loans in the cooperative's combined loan portfolio.
The CFC commented that the Commission should modify the language of
section 39.6(f)(2)(ii) (now Sec. 50.51(b)(2)), which is a cross-
reference to the definition of hedging or mitigating commercial risk
for the purposes of the end-user exception, to replace the term
``commercial enterprise'' with the term ``exempt cooperative.''
The requested change is not necessary. As explained in the final
release for the end-user exception,\43\ the use of the term
``commercial enterprise'' is intended to refer to the underlying
activity to which the risk being hedged or mitigated relates in the
context of the entity's normal business activities, not simply the type
of entity claiming the exemption. For example, in the context of the
cooperative exemption, it would include the risks undertaken by a
cooperative in the normal course of business of providing loans to
members.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\43\ 77 FR 42572 (July 19, 2012).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
D. Regulation 39.6(f)(3) (now Sec. 50.51(c)): Reporting
The Commission believes it is appropriate to impose certain
reporting requirements on any entities that may be exempted from the
clearing requirement by this regulation. The reporting requirements in
the final rule are effectively identical to the reporting requirements
for the end-user exception. For purposes of regulatory consistency,
Sec. 39.6(f)(3) (now Sec. 50.51(c)) incorporates the provisions of
Sec. 50.50(b) with only those changes needed to apply the reporting
provisions in the specific context of the cooperative exemption.
Regulation 50.50(b) requires one of the counterparties (the ``reporting
counterparty'') to provide, or cause to be provided, to a registered
SDR, or if no registered SDR is available, to the Commission,
information about how the counterparty electing the exception generally
expects to meet its financial obligations associated with non-cleared
swaps. In addition, Sec. 50.50(b) requires reporting of certain
information that the Commission will use to monitor compliance with,
and prevent abuse of, the exception. The reporting counterparty would
be required to provide the information at the time the electing
counterparty elects the cooperative exemption.
The CUNA requested that the Commission minimize the compliance
burdens on cooperatives that elect to use the cooperative exemption,
including the notification requirement. The ICBA requested that the
Commission modify the reporting requirement when the cooperative
exemption is elected. The ICBA commented that the aggregate reporting
requirements of Sec. 50.50(b) do not allow the Commission to ``monitor
actual risks or swaps usage.'' The ICBA stated that it was concerned
that FCS members actively seek to lend to a number of entities that are
not owners of the FCS. Because of this, the Commission, according to
the ICBA, would not have a way of verifying that the swaps for which an
FCS bank elected this exemption are actually eligible for the
cooperative exemption. Neither the ICBA nor the CUNA proposed any
specific changes to the rule text in connection with their comments.
The Commission has determined not to change the reporting
requirements proposed in Sec. 39.6(f)(3) (now Sec. 50.51(c)) and to
keep them consistent with the reporting requirements of the end-user
exception. The Commission discussed at length in the final release of
the end-user exception how the reporting requirements for entities
electing the clearing requirement exception are simplified through a
check-the-box approach and can be reported along with the other
reporting required for all swaps under the Commission's part 45
regulations.\44\ The Commission believes that the reporting
requirements will provide the Commission with sufficient information,
along with the other information to be reported for all swaps and
information publicly reported by cooperatives, to detect evasion of
required clearing or abuse of the exemption. For example, every swap
executed by a cooperative, as is the case with all swaps, must be
reported to an SDR or to the Commission and the parties to that swap
will be identified. Accordingly, the Commission will be able to review
and analyze the economic and other details of all swaps entered into by
each cooperative. As such, the Commission is able to monitor actual
swap usage by cooperatives. The swap reporting requirements are not
intended to monitor the risk levels of individual cooperatives.
Monitoring the accumulated risk undertaken by financial cooperatives is
generally the purview of their supervisory regulators.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\44\ 77 FR at 42565-70.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Based on a review of publicly available information and discussions
with the regulators of financial cooperatives, the Commission believes
that a large majority of lending by these cooperatives is to their
members. As such, at present there do not appear to be substantial
incentives for cooperatives to abuse the exemption with respect to
swaps that are not member related. Notwithstanding the foregoing, the
limitations on using the exemption for non-member related activities is
clearly established in the final rule and the Commission is confident
that the tools available to the Commission for addressing abuse or
evasion of the cooperative exemption are sufficient without changing
the reporting requirements as proposed.
E. Other Comments on the Proposed Rule
The ABA and the ICBA commented that the FCS, as a GSE, presents a
significant risk for the U.S. taxpayer. The ICBA stated that the FCS
was ``bailed out'' by the government during the farm credit crisis in
the 1980s. The ABA and the ICBA noted that the FCS,
[[Page 52295]]
if viewed as a single financial institution because of the mutual
support provisions for the FCS institutions, has assets worth more than
$230 billion. According to the ICBA, the FCS may be systemically
important under the Dodd-Frank Act because it has assets in excess of
$50 billion. The ICBA also suggested that the Commission should not
provide any exemptions for any institution with over $50 billion in
assets because institutions over $50 billion are considered to be
potentially systemically important under the Dodd-Frank Act.
In contrast, the FCC commented that the FCS banks have strong
protections in place for counterparty default, including, for example,
collateral posting agreements, which are overseen by the FCA. According
to the FCC, these protections have been effective throughout the recent
financial crisis. Accordingly, the FCC suggested that the FCS poses no
systemic risk to the U.S. financial system.
The fact that Congress designated the FCS as a GSE does not by
itself imply the existence of a sufficiently higher level of risk to
justify rejecting the limited exemption from clearing provided to
cooperatives. The Commission notes that the FCS is supervised by the
FCA, an independent Federal agency charged with overseeing the safety
and soundness of the FCS.\45\ The Commission acknowledged in the NPRM
that the proposed exemption would be available to cooperatives with
total assets in excess of $50 billion. However, the Commission believes
that the exemption, as narrowly drafted, is appropriate given the
benefits conferred by it to the entities Congress designated for the
end-user exception who are members of exempt cooperatives. Regarding
the possible designation of the FCS as systemically important, the
Commission notes that Congress excluded the possibility of the FCS from
being designated as systemically important by the Financial Stability
Oversight Council.\46\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\45\ See 12 U.S.C. 2241 (establishing the FCA); 12 U.S.C. 2252
(enumerating the powers of the FCA including the power to ensure the
safety and soundness of FCS institutions).
\46\ The Financial Stability Oversight Council does not have the
authority to determine that the FCS be supervised by the Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System as a ``nonbank financial
company'' pursuant to section 113 of the Dodd-Frank Act. The
definition of ``nonbank financial company'' includes a ``U.S.
nonbank financial company'' and a ``U.S. nonbank financial company''
specifically excludes a ``Farm Credit System institution chartered
and subject to the provisions of the Farm Credit Act of 1971.'' 12
U.S.C. 5311(a)(4); section 102(a)(4)(B) of the Dodd-Frank Act.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The CFC requested that the Commission, when coordinating with the
other prudential regulators working to finalize the margin rules for
non-cleared swaps, ensure that the final margin requirements for non-
cleared swaps are consistent with the final cooperative exemption. In
effect, the CFC requested that the final margin rules for non-cleared
swaps not require margin for swaps eligible for the cooperative
exemption.
The Commission intends to continue to work with the other
prudential regulators to ensure that the cooperative exemption, along
with other clearing exceptions or exemptions, are taken into
consideration when finalizing the margin rules for non-cleared swaps.
The ICBA suggested that the Commission should review the exemption
``every three years to see if the exemption is warranted on an ongoing
basis'' because cooperatives will have had time to ``adjust to the
evolving swaps markets and clearing systems.''
The Commission declines to include an explicit sunset or study
provision in the final rule. As the Commission's swap regulations are
new and the market is evolving in response, the Commission anticipates
evaluating its swap-related regulations on an as-needed basis and will
modify them as appropriate.
The ABA requested that the Commission extend the comment period for
this rule because of the ``impending regulatory deadlines, complexity,
and economic consequences'' of the cooperative exemption.
The Commission declines to extend the comment period because the
public was given an opportunity to, and did, participate in the
rulemaking process.
IV. Section 4(c) of the Commodity Exchange Act
Section 4(c)(1) of the CEA states that ``[i]n order to promote
responsible economic or financial innovation and fair competition'' the
CFTC may exempt any agreement, contract, or transaction subject to
section 4(a) from the requirements of that section or any other section
of the CEA. Section 4(c) authorizes the Commission to grant exemptive
relief to foster the development or continuance of market practices
that contribute to market innovation and competition.\47\ Congress, in
adding section 4(c) to the CEA, intended that the Commission, ``in
considering fair competition, will implement this provision in a fair
and even-handed manner.'' \48\ At the same time, Congress expected
that, in doing so, the Commission ``will apply consistent standards
based on the underlying facts and circumstances of the transaction and
markets being considered, and may make distinctions between exchanges
and other markets taking into account the particular facts and
circumstances involved, consistent with the public interest and the
purposes of the Act, where such distinctions are not arbitrary and
capricious.'' \49\ While this language refers specifically to
distinctions between exchanges and other markets, it implies that
Congress more generally expected the Commission, in applying section
4(c)(1), to draw distinctions among different market participants where
circumstances justify it.\50\ As discussed in detail elsewhere herein,
cooperatives are unique in their organizational form, in the way that
they act in the interests of their members, and in the well-established
public policies that support the ability of cooperative members to make
use of their cooperatives for purposes of accessing markets. These
unique characteristics justify an exemption specifically tailored to
enable non-financial entity end users that are members of cooperatives
to realize the full benefits of the end-user exception when they access
markets through their cooperatives.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\47\ See Conference Report, H.R. Report 102-978 at 8 (Oct. 2,
1992) (``The goal of providing the Commission with broad exemptive
powers . . . is to give the Commission a means of providing
certainty and stability to existing and emerging markets so that
financial innovation and market development can proceed in an
effective and competitive manner.'').
\48\ Id. at 78.
\49\ Id.
\50\ Cf., CEA section 4(c)(2)(A), 7 U.S.C. 6(c)(2)(A) (expressly
requiring a determination that an exemption from CEA section 4(a), 7
U.S.C. 6, under CEA section 4(c)(1), 7 U.S.C. 6(c)(1), be consistent
with the public interest and the purposes of the CEA, one of which
is ``to promote . . . fair competition . . . among . . . market
participants'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The end-user exception provided in section 2(h)(7) of the CEA is
not available to an entity that is a ``financial entity,'' as defined
in section 2(h)(7)(C)(i), unless the entity is exempt from the
definition because it is a small financial institution based on total
assets, as provided in section 2(h)(7)(C)(ii) of the CEA and Sec.
50.50(d), or it meets one of the narrowly drawn exemptions provided in
section 2(h)(7) or the Commission regulations. Section 2(h)(7)(C)(ii)
does not provide special consideration for cooperatives that meet the
definition of ``financial entity'' and, therefore, the asset size limit
applies to them.
As described in the NPRM and above, cooperatives whose member-
owners consist exclusively of persons or entities
[[Page 52296]]
that could elect the end-user exception provide important financial
services to their members. These cooperatives are, in many respects, an
extension of their member-owners and are not separable from their
members in any real sense because their mission is to act in the
interests of the members. However, some of those cooperatives meet the
definition of ``financial entity'' and have total assets in excess of
$10 billion, and therefore the end-user exception is unavailable to
them. By extension, the full benefits of the end-user exemption would
be unavailable to their members accessing financial services through
their cooperatives. Accordingly, absent this exemption, cooperative
members would lose the ability to use their cooperative for financial
services and at the same time, realize the full benefits of end-user
exception. Without the cooperative exemption, when a cooperative
engages in financial activity that could benefit from the end-user
exception and that activity is in the interest of the cooperative's
members, the members would not realize the full benefits of the end-
user exception because the cooperative cannot elect the exception.
Although the members of a cooperative may seek out financial services
from other market participants, some of which may be able to elect the
end-user exception, such members would not be able to realize the same
benefits as if they had acted through the cooperative. As previously
explained, such other market participants were not established solely
to serve the interests of its customers, and thus do not provide the
same benefits to its customers as the cooperative structure provides to
its members, even for similar services. Absent this exception, the
members of the cooperative would no longer be able to fully realize the
benefits for which the cooperatives were established of being the
members' intermediary in the financial markets acting in the mutual
interests of the members. In light of this, the Commission determined
to exercise its authority under section 4(c) of the CEA to propose
Sec. 39.6(f) (now Sec. 50.51) and establish the cooperative
exemption.
As noted above, section 4(c) of the CEA authorizes the Commission
to provide exemptions to classes of persons ``to promote responsible
economic or financial innovation and fair competition.'' Many of the
comments focused on this provision. For example, the ICBA commented
that the cooperative exemption does not promote financial innovation.
According to the ICBA, the Commission's estimate that the cooperative
exemption would affect 500 or less swaps a year shows that there is no
financial innovation by the exempt cooperatives. The ICBA also
commented that the Commission has not shown financial innovation
because the proposal excludes the FHL Banks, which, according to the
ICBA would potentially provide just as much, ``if not more,'' financial
innovation than an exemption for the FCS and credit unions. In essence,
the ICBA stated that the cooperative exemption does not promote
financial innovation because it is narrowly tailored and affects only a
small number of swaps and institutions. In contrast, the FCC commented
that ``[t]o provide tailored financing products for farmers and farm-
related businesses, FCS institutions rely on the safe use of
derivatives to manage interest rate, liquidity, and balance sheet risk,
primarily in the form of interest rate swaps.''
As discussed above in this section IV, Congress contemplated that
section 4(c) of the CEA would provide the Commission with the ``means
of providing certainty and stability to existing and emerging markets
so that financial innovation and market development can proceed in an
effective and competitive manner.'' \51\ Financial cooperatives have
existed for over 100 years and were given separate legal status by
Congress as far back as 1916.\52\ Without these cooperatives, members
have less choice in where they can borrow capital and hedge risks
related to those borrowing activities. Swaps are a fairly recent
innovation in the financial markets that has become an integral part of
borrowing and lending. The cooperative form has enabled members to
manage their borrowing activities and to use swaps to hedge risks in
connection therewith at a lower cost. By pooling member capital in
financial cooperatives, members are in effect aggregating their
resources to allow them not only to gain a lower cost of funding, but
also to be able to hire experienced executives who, as employees of the
cooperative, are charged with managing the financial activities of the
cooperative and advising the board of directors of the cooperative for
the benefit of the member-owners, who often have specific, shared
purposes that are the mission focus of the cooperative.\53\ Further,
because the cooperative members elect the board members of the
cooperative on a democratic, one member, one vote, basis,\54\ and often
most, if not all, board members are cooperative members,\55\ the
membership, through the governing board, has a unique opportunity to
better understand the benefits and risks of swaps used in connection
with their financial activities and as a group control the thoughtful
application thereof in a responsible manner and for their mutual
benefit. The mutual benefit of pooling resources and acting
cooperatively is one of the principal policy reasons for the
establishment of cooperative structures.\56\ These are benefits that
the cooperative member-owners would not have as customers of other
financial institutions that they do not own or control and that are not
established with the mission of providing financing and financial
services to a particular type of customer and for their benefit.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\51\ See Conference Report, H.R. Report 102-978 at 8 (October 2,
1992).
\52\ See The Federal Farm Loan Act, Public Law 64-158, 39 Stat.
360 (1916) (repealed 1923) (a predecessor to the Farm Credit Act).
\53\ See, e.g., the mission statement of the Farm Credit Bank of
Texas: ``Other lenders may lend to agriculture and rural America
only when it is profitable to do so, but at Farm Credit, financing
rural America is all we do. When Congress created the Farm Credit
System in 1916, it gave the System a mission to be a competitive,
reliable source of funds for eligible borrowers in agriculture and
rural America. Because we specialize in these areas, we have
expertise that is unparalleled among other lenders.'' https://www.farmcreditbank.com/farm-credit-advantage.aspx; See also CoBank
2011 Annual Report, 31 (``We are a mission-based lender with
authority to make loans and provide related financial services to
eligible borrowers in the agribusiness and rural utility industries,
and to certain related entities, as defined by the Farm Credit Act.
. . . We are cooperatively owned by our U.S. customers.'').
\54\ To receive treatment as cooperatives under the Internal
Revenue Code, an entity must be ``operating on a cooperative
basis.'' 26 U.S.C. 1381(a). The United States Tax Court has held
that one of the guiding principles for determining whether an entity
is operating on a cooperative basis is if it is democratically
controlled by the members. Puget Sound Plywood, Inc. v.
Commissioner, 44 T.C. 305, 308 (1965).
\55\ See, e.g., 12 U.S.C. 2072, 92 (requiring boards for
production credit associations and federal land bank associations be
selected from its voting members); 12 CFR 701 app. A (bylaws for
national credit unions requiring board members be members of the
credit union); Kan. Stat. Ann. Sec. 17-1510 (West) (requiring board
members to be selected from the membership); Va. Code Ann. Sec.
13.1-324 (West) (requiring the board, except for the public
director, consist of members).
\56\ See, e.g., the initial statement of Congress in the Farm
Credit System Act, which authorizes the Farm Credit System that the
FCS cooperatives are a part of: ``It is the objective of this
chapter to continue to encourage farmer- and rancher-borrowers
participation in the management, control, and ownership of a
permanent system of credit for agriculture which will be responsive
to the credit needs of all types of agricultural producers having a
basis for credit, and to modernize and improve the authorizations
and means for furnishing such credit and credit for housing in rural
areas made available through the institutions constituting the Farm
Credit System as herein provided.'' 12 U.S.C. 2001.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
In addition, section 4(c) of the CEA does not specify that the
financial
[[Page 52297]]
innovation realized must be of a certain size. Innovation often begins
on a small scale before becoming widely accepted and implemented, if
successful. Regarding whether the FHL Banks should be included because
the exemption would also provide innovation through the FHL Banks, as
described in detail above in section III.B of this final release, the
Commission determined to carefully narrow the cooperatives that can
elect the exemption to those whose members consist exclusively of
entities that (or other cooperatives whose members) do qualify for the
end-user exception on their own, given the clear Congressional intent
in section 2(h)(7) of the CEA to exclude financial entities (the
definition of which excludes small financial institutions) from the
end-user exception to the clearing requirement. Given that FHL Banks
are not made up exclusively of non-financial entities or small
financial institutions, the cooperative exemption would not be
available to them.
The ABA and ICBA also commented that the cooperative exemption does
not qualify under section 4(c) and is discriminatory because it would
give cooperatives a competitive advantage over banks and therefore it
does not promote ``fair competition.'' They also commented that
cooperatives compete with banks for the same business opportunities,
and as GSEs and tax-exempt entities, cooperatives can offer more
competitive pricing than traditional banks. Lake City Bank commented
that it has difficulty competing with the FCS and credit unions for
business due to the GSE status of the FCS, the large amount of assets
the FCS maintains, and the favorable tax status afforded to the FCS and
credit unions.
In contrast, the FCC commented that the cooperative exemption
preserves a ``level field for FCS institutions and commercial banks''
that qualify for the end-user exception because FCS associations that
otherwise would qualify as small financial institutions and compete
with qualifying banks hedge risk at the level of the FCS bank
cooperatives in which they are members. In effect, the FCC asserts that
the FCS associations would be unable to use the end-user exception
because the cooperative structure of the FCS system means that the
associations act through the FCS bank cooperatives (all of which have
total assets over $10 billion) for their hedging activities and not
directly.
As discussed previously, the essential function of cooperatives is
to enable their members to access markets through a commonly-owned
intermediary. The memberships of the cooperatives that would qualify
for the cooperative exemption consist of entities that can elect the
end-user exception if acting on their own or other cooperatives the
members of which can elect the end-user exception. However, these
cooperatives meet the definition of ``financial entity'' and are too
large to qualify for the small financial institution exemption, which,
in turn, renders the end-user exception unavailable to the
cooperatives. Accordingly, if the cooperative members wish to access
the markets through their financial cooperative, which has been
established for that same purpose, they would not receive the full
benefits of the end-user exception because the cooperative would have
to clear its swaps even though it is acting in the interests of its
members in the markets. On the other hand, the members could enter into
loans and swaps with other financial entities that can elect the end-
user exception. In effect, the cooperative structure, which is intended
to give the members the benefit of size by allowing them to pool their
resources and act together for their mutual benefit, instead would
frustrate their ability to realize the full benefits of the end-user
exception when acting through their cooperatives. As such, the
cooperative exemption seeks to preserve the benefits available to the
members of cooperatives as intended under the cooperative legal
structure.
The Commission's recognition that the cooperatives provide a means
for its members to access the financial markets in a variety of ways is
consistent with the intent of Congress and state legislatures in the
laws establishing cooperative legal structures. As described below,
some of these laws acknowledge that cooperatives may have certain
benefits or advantages that other entities do not have, but that any
such advantages are acceptable for promoting the benefits of
cooperatives because ultimately the benefits inure to the members of
the cooperatives. The cooperative exemption is being adopted by the
Commission in the context of the foregoing policy determinations.\57\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\57\ As an example of these legislative policy determinations,
the Federal Credit Union Act states:
The Congress finds the following:
(1) The American credit union movement began as a cooperative
effort to serve the productive and provident credit needs of
individuals of modest means.
(2) Credit unions continue to fulfill this public purpose, and
current members and membership groups should not face divestiture
from the financial services institution of their choice as a result
of recent court action.
(3) To promote thrift and credit extension, a meaningful
affinity and bond among members, manifested by a commonality of
routine interaction, shared and related work experiences, interests,
or activities, or the maintenance of an otherwise well understood
sense of cohesion or identity is essential to the fulfillment of the
public mission of credit unions.
(4) Credit unions, unlike many other participants in the
financial services market, are exempt from Federal and most State
taxes because they are member-owned, democratically operated, not-
for-profit organizations generally managed by volunteer boards of
directors and because they have the specified mission of meeting the
credit and savings needs of consumers, especially persons of modest
means.
(5) Improved credit union safety and soundness provisions will
enhance the public benefit that citizens receive from these
cooperative financial services institutions.
12 U.S.C. 1751. State cooperative laws also acknowledge the
different status cooperatives are being provided within the
competitive landscape. See N.Y. Coop. Corp. Law, which states that:
``[a] cooperative corporation shall be classed as a non-profit
corporation, since its primary object is not to make profits for
itself as such, or to pay dividends on invested capital, but to
provide service and means whereby its members may have the economic
advantage of cooperative action, including a reasonable and fair
return for their product and service.'' N.Y. Coop. Corp. Law 3
(McKinney) (emphasis added); see also Ky. Rev. Stat. Ann. Sec.
272.1001(2) (West 2012).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Importantly, the Commission notes that the swaps that are the
subject of the exemption are limited to those swaps related to member
loans. Accordingly, the exemption applies only to the swaps related to
lending services that financial cooperatives have been established to
provide, and traditionally do provide, to their owner-members.\58\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\58\ For example, with respect to the FCS, the Farm Credit Act
of 1971 provides, ``It is declared to be the policy of the Congress,
recognizing that a prosperous, productive agriculture is essential
to a free nation and recognizing the growing need for credit in
rural areas, that the farmer-owned cooperative Farm Credit System be
designed to accomplish the objective of improving the income and
well-being of American farmers and ranchers by furnishing sound,
adequate, and constructive credit and closely related services to
them, their cooperatives, and to selected farm-related businesses
necessary for efficient farm operations.'' 12 U.S.C. 2001.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The ABA and ICBA also cited to ``preferred tax and funding
advantages as [GSEs]'' for FCS banks and the tax-exempt status that
qualifying cooperatives have under Subchapter T of the Federal Internal
Revenue Code (``Tax Code'') as existing advantages cooperatives have
over banks. On the other hand, financial cooperatives, such as the FCS
and credit unions, are subject to other legal restrictions and
regulated by their own regulators, who may impose restrictions that put
them at a competitive disadvantage when compared to banks. For example,
federal statutes and regulations applicable to FCS cooperatives
restrict lending services to particular classes of borrowers, prohibit
them from taking deposits (which limits their funding sources as
compared to banks), and
[[Page 52298]]
limit other services that they can provide to members. Similarly, the
Tax Code, U.S. Tax Court rulings, and other guidance from the Internal
Revenue Service impose limits on the business structure of cooperatives
that seek cooperative tax treatment under the Tax Code that may impact
their competitiveness. Also, cooperatives generally cannot raise equity
capital from independent, non-customer investors. While the
Commission's role is not to determine the relative overall competitive
advantages or disadvantages that cooperatives or other financial
institutions may have, the Commission believes that any limited
advantage the cooperative exemption may provide to exempt cooperatives
is likely to be small when viewed in the context of the complete
competitive landscape in which financial cooperatives and banks
operate.
Given that Sec. 39.6(f) (now Sec. 50.51) and its attendant terms
and conditions would (1) promote economic and financial innovation for
the benefit of the members of exempt cooperatives, (2) foster the
ability of cooperative members to access the financial markets through
their cooperatives and (3) further Congressional intent by providing a
limited exemption from clearing that effectively extends the end-user
exception to cooperatives that have end users for members, the
Commission concludes that the adoption of Sec. 39.6(f) (now Sec.
50.51) and its attendant terms and conditions would promote responsible
economic and financial innovation and fair competition in accordance
with section 4(c) of the CEA.
The Commission also concludes that the cooperative exemption will
be limited to entities that fall within the term ``appropriate
person,'' as required by section 4(c)(2)(B)(i) of the CEA.\59\ Section
2(e) of the CEA renders it ``unlawful for any person, other than an
[eligible contract participant (``ECP'')], to enter into a swap unless
the swap is entered into on, or subject to the rules of, a board of
trade designated as a contract market.'' \60\ Since the cooperative
exemption can only be elected for swaps that are executed bilaterally
and not on a board of trade or contract market, both the exempt
cooperatives and their respective counterparties to such swaps must be
ECPs. Given that the criteria for the ECP definition covering business
organizations generally is more restrictive than the comparable
criteria for the appropriate person definition in section 4(c)(3),\61\
the Commission finds that the class of persons relying on Sec.
50.51(a) will be limited to appropriate persons for purposes of CEA
section 4(c)(2)(B)(i).\62\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\59\ 7 U.S.C. 6(c)(2)(B)(i).
\60\ 7 U.S.C. 2(e).
\61\ Compare CEA section 4(c)(3)(F) identifying the applicable
type of appropriate person (a ``corporation, partnership,
proprietorship, organization, trust, or other business entity with a
net worth exceeding $1,000,000 or total assets exceeding $5,000,000
. . .'' and section 1a(18)(A)(v) that identifies a comparable type
of ECP (a ``corporation, partnership, proprietorship, organization,
trust, or other entity'' with a net worth exceeding $1,000,000 (and
that enters into an agreement, contract or transaction for certain
risk management purposes) or total assets exceeding $10,000,000).
\62\ Although Sec. 39.6(f) (now Sec. 50.51) is an exemption
from the clearing requirement of section 2(h)(1)(A) of the CEA and
section 2(e) of the CEA sets forth a standard for entering into a
swap, section 4(c)(2)(B)(i) requires that any agreement, contract or
transaction that is the subject of a CEA section 4(c)(1) exemption
be ``entered into'' solely between appropriate persons. Therefore,
focusing on section 2(e), which is an execution standard rather than
a clearing standard, is appropriate, particularly given that if it
is unlawful to enter into a swap in the first instance, the clearing
requirement is moot.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Furthermore, the Commission concludes that the cooperative
exemption will not have a material adverse effect on the ability of the
Commission or any contract market or derivatives transaction execution
facility to discharge their respective regulatory duties under the CEA
as provided in section 4(c)(2)(B)(ii) of the CEA. The cooperative
exemption effectively extends the end-user exception established in
section 2(h)(7) of the CEA to cooperatives acting for non-financial
entities. Section 39.6(f)(3) (now Sec. 50.51(c)) has the same
reporting requirement that the end-user exception has with the only
difference being that the reporting party must report that the
cooperative exemption has been elected for the swap being reported
instead of the end-user exception. In this way, the Commission will be
able to track the swaps for which the cooperative exemption is being
elected and who is electing the exemption thereby allowing the
Commission to oversee the use of the cooperative exemption in the same
manner as the end-user exception. Regarding contract markets and
derivatives transaction execution facilities, the cooperative exemption
does not modify their regulatory duties under the CEA. Accordingly,
those entities will not have any increase or reduction in their
regulatory duties with regard to the exempted swaps.
V. Administrative Procedure Act Related Comments
The ABA and the ICBA submitted a number of comments asserting that
the rule is discriminatory or violates the arbitrary and capricious
standard in the APA.\63\ The ABA commented that the Commission did not
provide a reasonable explanation for why cooperatives with over $10
billion in total assets were given an exemption while banks with total
assets over $10 billion were not. According to the ABA, the Commission
did not take into account the Congressional intent not to exempt banks
and cooperatives with total assets above $10 billion from mandatory
clearing.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\63\ See 5 U.S.C. 706(2)(A).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The Commission disagrees with the commenters' assertion that the
Commission did not provide a reasonable explanation for the rule or
that it does not fulfill Congressional intent. As discussed throughout
the NPRM and as reiterated in this final release in response to
specific comments, the cooperative exemption fulfills Congressional
intent as expressed in section 2(h)(7) of the CEA by providing the full
benefits of the end-user exception to the end-user members of
cooperatives who act in the markets through their cooperatives. The
limitation on the definition of ``exempt cooperative'' to those
cooperatives whose members consist exclusively of entities and persons
who may elect the end-user exception and other cooperatives whose
members meet that requirement makes that readily apparent and is
explained in detail in the NPRM.\64\ Furthermore, the Commission
considered both this element of Congressional intent and Congress'
clear mandate that the Commission require that certain swaps entered
into by financial institutions be cleared by carefully and purposefully
limiting the types of swaps for which the cooperative exemption is
available.\65\ The Commission's reasoning behind the cooperative
exemption based on the unique member-owner structure of cooperatives
and the nature of cooperatives as entities whose primary purpose is to
act in the interests of their member-owners in the financial
marketplace is thoroughly discussed throughout the NPRM and reiterated
in this final release. Commenters' assertions that the cooperative
exemption rule is inconsistent with Congressional intent or is
arbitrary and capricious are therefore without merit.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\64\ 77 FR 41942 and 41943, and section III.B above.
\65\ 77 FR 41942 and 41943, and section III.C above.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
[[Page 52299]]
VI. Consideration of Costs and Benefits
A. Background
In the wake of the financial crisis of 2008, Congress adopted the
Dodd-Frank Act, which, among other things, requires the Commission to
determine whether a particular swap, or group, category, type or class
of swaps, shall be required to be cleared.\66\ Specifically, section
723(a)(3) of the Dodd-Frank Act amended section 2(h)(1)(A) of the CEA
to make it ``unlawful for any person to engage in a swap unless that
person submits such swap for clearing to a [DCO] that is registered
under the CEA or a [DCO] that is exempt from registration under [the
CEA] if the swap is required to be cleared.'' This clearing requirement
is designed to reduce counterparty risk associated with swaps and, in
turn, mitigate the potential systemic impact of such risk and reduce
the likelihood for swaps to cause or exacerbate instability in the
financial system.\67\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\66\ See section 2(h)(2) of the CEA, 7 U.S.C. 2(h)(2).
\67\ When a bilateral swap is moved into clearing, the DCO
becomes the counterparty to each of the original participants in the
swap. This standardizes counterparty risk for the original swap
participants in that they each bear the same risk attributable to
facing the DCO as counterparty. In addition, DCOs exist for the
primary purpose of managing credit exposure from the swaps being
cleared and therefore DCOs are effective at mitigating counterparty
risk through the use of risk management frameworks. These frameworks
model risk and collect defined levels of initial and variation
margin from the counterparties that are adjusted for changing market
conditions and use guarantee funds and other risk management tools
for the purpose of assuring that, in the event of a member default,
all other counterparties remain whole. DCOs have demonstrated
resilience in the face of past market stress. Most recently, they
remained financially sound and effectively settled positions in the
midst of turbulent events in 2007-2008 that threatened the financial
health and stability of many other types of entities and the
financial system as a whole. These, and other benefits of clearing,
are explained more fully at: 77 FR 74284.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Notwithstanding the benefits of clearing, section 2(h)(7) of the
CEA provides the end-user exception if one of the swap counterparties:
``(i) is not a financial entity; (ii) is using swaps to hedge or
mitigate commercial risk; and (iii) notifies the Commission, in a
manner set forth by the Commission, how it generally meets its
financial obligations associated with entering into non-cleared
swaps.'' Section 2(h)(7)(C)(ii) of the CEA directs the Commission to
consider making the end-user exception available to small banks,
savings associations, credit unions, and farm credit institutions,
including those institutions with total assets of $10 billion or less,
through an exemption from the definition of ``financial entity.'' \68\
In Sec. 39.6(d) (now Sec. 50.50(d)), the Commission established the
small financial institution exemption from the definition of
``financial entity'' for these institutions. The small financial
institution exemption largely adopted the language of section
2(h)(7)(C)(ii) providing for an exemption for the institutions
identified in section 2(h)(7)(C)(ii) that have total assets of $10
billion or less.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\68\ See section 2(h)(7)(C)(ii) of the CEA.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
On December 23, 2010, the Commission published for public comment
an NPRM for Sec. 39.6 (now Sec. 50.50) proposing the end-user
exception.\69\ As discussed in section I hereof, several parties that
commented on the end-user exception NPRM recommended that the
Commission provide extend the end-user exception to cooperatives. These
commenters reasoned \70\ that the member ownership structure of
cooperatives and the fact that they act in the interests of members
that are non-financial entities justified an extension of the end-user
exception to the cooperatives. In effect, the commenters posited that
because a cooperative effectively acts as an intermediary for its
members when facing the larger financial markets with its interests
being effectively the same as its members' interests, the end-user
exception that would be available to a cooperative's members should
also be available to the cooperative. If the members themselves could
elect the end-user exception, then, according to the commenters, the
Commission should permit the cooperatives to do so as well.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\69\ See 75 FR 80747.
\70\ Other reasons given for providing an exemption from
clearing for cooperatives are discussed above in this final rule.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The Commission is adopting the cooperative exemption herein as
described in this release. Through Sec. 39.6(f) (now Sec. 50.51), the
Commission uses the authority provided in section 4(c) of the CEA to
permit ``exempt cooperatives,'' as defined in Sec. 39.6(f)(1) (now
Sec. 50.51(a)) to elect not to clear certain swaps that are otherwise
required to be cleared pursuant to section 2(h)(1)(A) of the CEA. In
effect, the cooperative exemption makes available to exempt
cooperatives the end-user exception that is available to their members,
as described in greater detail above.\71\ It is the costs and benefits
of this exemption that the Commission considered in the discussion that
follows.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\71\ Exempt cooperatives can be financial entities that do not
qualify for the small financial institution exemption because their
assets exceed $10 billion. As provided in Sec. 39.6(f)(2) (now
Sec. 50.51(b)) of the rule, an exempt cooperative would not be
required to clear swaps with members in connection with originating
member loans, or swaps used by the exempt cooperative to hedge or
mitigate commercial risk arising in connection with such swaps with
members or loans to members.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
B. Statutory Requirement To Consider the Costs and Benefits of the
Commission's Action: CEA Section 15(a)
Section 15(a) of the CEA requires the Commission to consider the
costs and benefits of its actions before promulgating a regulation
under the CEA or issuing certain orders. Section 15(a) further
specifies that the costs and benefits shall be evaluated in light of
the following five broad areas of market and public concern: (1)
Protection of market participants and the public; (2) efficiency,
competitiveness and financial integrity of futures markets; (3) price
discovery; (4) sound risk management practices; and (5) other public
interest considerations. Accordingly, the Commission considers the
costs and benefits resulting from its own discretionary determinations
with respect to the section 15(a) factors.
Absent this rulemaking, all cooperatives that are financial
entities as defined in section 2(h)(7)(C)(i) of the CEA and which are
not otherwise exempt from that definition would be subject to the
clearing requirement under section 2(h)(7)(A)(i) of the CEA. Thus, the
scenario against which this rulemaking's costs and benefits are
considered is cooperatives within the definition of financial entity in
Section 2(h)(7)(C)(i) with assets exceeding $10 billion, which remain
subject to the clearing requirement of section 2(h)(1)(A) of the CEA.
Additionally, the Commission considers the rulemaking's costs and
benefits relative to alternatives considered by the Commission.
As discussed in more detail below, the Commission is able to
estimate certain reporting costs. The dollar estimates are offered as
ranges with upper and lower bounds, which is necessary to accommodate
the uncertainty that surrounds them. The discussion below considers the
rule's costs and benefits as well as alternatives to the rule. The
discussion concludes with a consideration of the rule's costs and
benefits in light of the five factors specified in section 15(a) of the
CEA.
C. Costs and Benefits of the Final Rule
1. Costs and Benefits to Electing Cooperatives and Their Members
Providing an exemption from required clearing to cooperatives that
meet the criteria described in the final rule will benefit them and
their members in that they will not have to bear the costs of
[[Page 52300]]
clearing that they would otherwise incur. Without the cooperative
exemption rule, cooperatives meeting the criteria of the exemption
would have to clear swaps pursuant to section 2(h)(1)(A) of the CEA
when they are either: (1) Entering into a swap with a member that is
subject to required clearing, or (2) transacting with another financial
entity to hedge or mitigate risk related to loans with members or swaps
with members related to such loans. Required clearing would introduce
additional costs for cooperatives, including fees associated with
clearing as well as costs associated with margin and capital
requirements.
Regarding fees, DCOs typically charge Futures Commission Merchants
(``FCMs'') an initial transaction fee for each of the FCM customers'
swaps that are cleared, as well as an annual maintenance fee for each
of their customers' open positions.\72\ As a result, cooperatives
eligible for the exemption will bear lower costs related to swaps and
would likely pass along these costs savings to their members either by
providing swaps at more attractive rates or through larger patronage
distributions or allocations.\73\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\72\ For example, not including customer-specific and volume
discounts, the transaction fees for interest rate swaps at CME range
from $1 to $24 per million notional amount and the maintenance fees
are $2 per year per million notional amount for open positions. LCH
transaction fees for interest rate swaps range from $1 to $20 per
million notional amount, and the maintenance fee ranges from $5 to
$20 per swap per month, depending on the number of outstanding swap
positions that an entity has with the DCO. See LCH pricing for
clearing services related to OTC interest rate swaps at: https://www.lchclearnet.com/swaps/swapclear_for_clearing_members/fees.asp.
\73\ The CUNA stated that the exemption ``would help minimize
the additional costs and fees associated with mandatory clearing.''
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The ABA questioned whether the exemption would have benefits that
accrue to members of exempt cooperatives. The ABA stated that in the
absence of the proposed exemption, cooperative members can still exempt
their swaps from clearing. Therefore, the ABA believes that ``the
proposed clearing exemption would solely benefit cooperatives larger
than $10 billion.''
The Commission, however, anticipates that benefits will accrue to
members of exempt cooperatives. Generally, as discussed in section IV,
the mission of the cooperatives is to provide loans and other financial
services to particular types of borrowers and the cooperatives operate
for the mutual benefit of their respective members. As such, in keeping
with its mission and purpose, a cooperative is likely to elect the
exemption only if the election thereof benefits its members. As
discussed further in this section VI, the exemption is likely to lower
operational costs for exempt cooperatives and to reduce their margin
requirements. As a consequence, exempt cooperatives will be able to
provide lower-cost funding to their members, to retain more member
allocable capital, or to pay out higher patronage distributions to
their members. Ultimately, the members, as owners of the cooperatives,
will benefit.
Regarding margin requirements, by allowing cooperatives to exempt
certain swaps from clearing, the final rule may reduce the amount of
margin that exempt cooperatives and their counterparties are required
to post for swaps used to hedge or mitigate risk associated with loans
to eligible members and for swaps related to those loans.\74\ Reduced
margin requirements will reduce the amount of capital that exempt
cooperatives must allocate to margin, which will increase the amount of
capital that exempt cooperatives may distribute or allocate to members.
On the other hand, to the extent that the exemption results in exempt
cooperatives and their counterparties holding less margin against
exempt swap positions, each will be exposed to greater counterparty
risk.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\74\ The Commission notes that regulations addressing margin and
capital requirements for non-cleared swaps have not yet been
finalized. Accordingly, the Commission cannot determine, quantify,
or estimate what margin, if any, may be required for the swaps
exempted from clearing under the cooperative exemption.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The final rule may also affect the capital that cooperatives that
are financial entities are required to hold with respect to their swap
positions pursuant to prudential regulatory capital requirements. As
stated above, when compared to a situation in which the cooperative
exemption is not available, the cooperative exemption will reduce the
number of swaps that exempt cooperatives are required to clear. The
Commission anticipates that reducing the number of swaps that such
cooperatives clear may impact the amount of capital that exempt
cooperatives are required to hold. This creates both benefits and
costs. If reduced clearing lowers the amount of capital that exempt
cooperatives must hold, that would increase the cooperative's lending
capacity, enabling them to lend more to their members without retaining
or raising additional capital. As for costs, this allows exempt
cooperatives to become more highly leveraged, which increases the
counterparty risk that they pose to their members and other market
participants with whom they transact. On the other hand, if reduced
clearing increases the amount of capital that exempt cooperatives must
hold, that would have the opposite effect.
Cooperatives that elect the exemption will be required to report,
or to cause to be reported, additional information to an SDR or to the
Commission, which will create incremental costs for the reporting
party. The final rule requires that exempt cooperatives adhere to the
reporting requirements of Sec. 50.50(b). For each swap where the
exemption is elected, either the exempt cooperative or its counterparty
(likely if the counterparty is an SD or MSP) must report: (1) That the
election of the exemption is being made; (2) which party is the
electing counterparty; and (3) certain information specific to the
electing counterparty unless that information has already been provided
by the electing counterparty through an annual filing.\75\ In addition,
for entities that are registered with the SEC, the reporting party will
also be required to report with respect to the electing counterparty:
(1) The SEC filer's central index key number; and (2) that an
appropriate committee of the board of directors has approved the
decision for that entity to enter into swaps that are exempt from the
requirements of sections 2(h)(1) and 2(h)(8) of the Act.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\75\ The third set of information comprises data that is likely
to remain relatively constant and therefore, does not require swap-
by-swap reporting and can be reported less frequently.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
For each exempted swap, to comply with the swap-by-swap reporting
requirements in Sec. Sec. 50.50(b)(1)(i) and (ii), the reporting
counterparty will be required to check one box indicating the exemption
is being elected and complete one field identifying the electing
counterparty. The Commission expects that this information will be
entered into the appropriate reporting system concurrently with
additional information that is required by the CEA and part 45 of the
Commission's regulations. Furthermore, the Commission estimates that
there will be approximately 500 swaps per year that are exempted from
clearing pursuant to this rule.\76\ Therefore, each reporting
[[Page 52301]]
counterparty is likely to spend 15 seconds to 2 minutes per transaction
in incremental time entering the swap-by-swap information into the
reporting system, or in the aggregate, 1.5 hours to 17 hours per year
for all 500 estimated swaps. A financial analyst's average salary is
$208/hour, which corresponds to approximately $1-$7 per transaction or
in aggregate, $300-$3,500 per year for all 500 estimated swaps.\77\
While the above information must be reported on a swap-by-swap basis,
some information may be reported annually. Regulation Sec.
50.50(b)(1)(iii) allows for certain counterparty specific information
identified therein to be reported either swap-by-swap by the reporting
counterparty or annually by the electing counterparty. When exempt
cooperatives enter into exempt swaps with members, the cooperative is
likely to be the reporting counterparty. Furthermore, assuming the
cooperative is the reporting counterparty, the time burden for the
first swap entered into by an exempt cooperative in collecting and
reporting the information required by Sec. 50.50(b)(1)(iii) will be
approximately the same as the time burden for collecting and reporting
the information for the annual filing. Given the cost equivalence for
annual reporting to reporting a single swap if the exempt cooperative
is both the electing and reporting counterparty, the Commission assumes
that all ten exempt cooperatives will make an annual filing of the
information required for Sec. 50.50(b)(1)(iii). The Commission
estimates that it will take an average of 30 minutes to 90 minutes to
complete and submit the annual filing. The average hourly wage for a
compliance attorney is $300, which means that the annual per
cooperative cost for the filing is likely to be between $150 and $450.
If all ten exempt cooperatives were to undertake an annual filing, the
aggregate cost would be $1,500 to $4,500.\78\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\76\ A review of information provided for five cooperatives that
likely would be exempt cooperatives showed a range of swap usage
from none to as many as approximately 200 swaps a year with most
entering into less than 50 swaps a year. Using the high end of
reported swaps for the five cooperatives for which information was
available, an estimate of 50 swaps per year was calculated. The
Commission believes this estimate is high because some of the
reported swaps may not meet the requirements of the final rule and,
based on discussions with other regulators, several cooperatives for
which detailed information was not available to the Commission
likely undertake little, if any, swap activity. However, for
purposes of the cost calculations, the Commission assumes that each
of the 10 potential exempt cooperatives will enter into 50 swaps
each year. Accordingly, it is estimated that exempt cooperatives may
elect the cooperative exemption for 500 swaps each year.
\77\ Wage estimates are taken from the SIFMA ``Report on
Management and Professional Earnings in the Securities Industry
2011.'' Hourly wages are calculated assuming 1,800 hours per year
and a multiplier of 5.35 to account for overhead and bonuses. In
light of the challenges of developing precise estimates, the results
of calculations have been rounded.
\78\ The average wage for a compliance attorney is $300.95
[($112,505 per year)/(2,000 hours per year) * 5.35 = $300.95]. For
the purposes of the Cost Benefit Considerations section, the
Commission has used wage estimates that are taken from the SIFMA
``Report on Management and Professional Earnings in the Securities
Industry 2011'' because industry participants are likely to be more
familiar with them. Hourly costs are calculated assuming 2,000 hours
per year and a multiplier of 5.35 to account for overhead and
bonuses. All totals calculated on the basis of cost estimates are
rounded to two significant digits.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Furthermore, when an exempt cooperative is not functioning as the
reporting counterparty (i.e., when transacting with a SD or MSP), it
may, at certain times, need to communicate information to its reporting
counterparties in order to facilitate reporting. That information may
include, among other things, whether the electing counterparty has
filed an annual report pursuant to Sec. 50.50(b) and information to
facilitate any due diligence that the reporting counterparty may
conduct. These costs will likely vary substantially depending on the
number of different reporting counterparties with whom an electing
counterparty conducts transactions, how frequently the electing
counterparty enters into swaps, whether the electing counterparty
undertakes an annual filing, and the due diligence that the reporting
counterparty chooses to conduct. The Commission estimates that non-
reporting electing counterparties will incur between 5 minutes and 10
hours of annual burden hours, or in the aggregate, between
approximately 1 hour and 100 hours. The hourly wage for a compliance
attorney is $300, which means that the annual aggregate cost for
communicating information to the reporting counterparty is likely to be
between $300 and $30,000. Given the unknowns associated with this cost
estimate noted above, the Commission does not believe this wide range
can be narrowed without further information.\79\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\79\ As noted above, the average wage for a compliance attorney
is $300.95 per hour [($112,505 per year)/(2,000 hours per year) *
5.35 = $300.95].
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The ABA and the ICBA suggested that the Commission's assumption
that each potentially exempt cooperative engages in 50 swaps a year
does not take into account the fact that the number of swaps entered
into by the exempt cooperatives may change or increase over time. The
ABA also commented that the Commission underestimated the number of
cooperatives eligible and assumes that the number of cooperatives would
not increase by either reorganization or growth.
The Commission contacted the FCA and National Credit Union
Administration for further assistance in assessing whether the
estimates used in the NPRM are reasonable. These regulators discussed
generally the observed level of swap activity of the cooperatives they
regulate. Based on these discussions, the Commission concluded that the
estimates in the NPRM are reasonable and appropriate for this
rulemaking. The Commission recognizes that the number of entities
eligible for the exemption and the number of swaps per eligible
cooperative is likely to change in the future and that the benefits of
this exemption for exempt cooperatives could encourage the number or
size of exempt cooperatives and of swaps used by those cooperatives to
grow. However, the Commission notes that the extent to which such
growth is realized also depends on several additional factors that the
Commission does not have adequate information to evaluate, including:
(1) Subsequent changes to laws or regulations affecting one or more
types of cooperatives; (2) increases or decreases in the size of the
industries served by those cooperatives; and (3) the frequency with
which exempt cooperatives make loans or experience other changes that
require rebalancing of their hedging strategies. Because the Commission
does not have sufficient information to estimate the direction or
magnitude of the effect that these forces will have on the number of
exempt cooperatives and exempt swaps per cooperative, it is not
possible to evaluate how future changes in either are likely to affect
the costs or benefits related to the exemption.
2. Costs and Benefits for Counterparties to Electing Cooperatives
The benefits of the exemption for counterparties to electing exempt
cooperatives differ depending on whether they are members of the
cooperatives. For entities that are members of the electing
cooperative, they will likely benefit from the reduced operational
costs the exempt cooperative achieves through reduced clearing fees
associated with the cooperative's swaps with the market. The benefit
may be passed on in the form of better terms on swaps between members
and the cooperative and through the cooperative's patronage
distributions to members. For entities that are not members of the
cooperative (i.e. market makers entering into swaps with the
cooperative), the benefits are different. Market makers entering into
swaps with cooperatives that are subject to the exemption do not
participate in the pro rata patronage distributions, but may benefit
from reduced clearing costs associated with non-cleared swaps.
Reduced clearing of swaps by exempt cooperatives will increase
counterparty risk for both exempt cooperatives and their
counterparties. Cooperatives will be more exposed to the credit risk of
their counterparties, and conversely, the cooperatives' counterparties
will be more exposed to the credit risk of the exempt cooperatives.
This could be
[[Page 52302]]
problematic for an exempt cooperative if one of the dealers with which
the cooperative has large non-cleared positions defaults, or if groups
of members whose financial strength may be highly correlated and whose
aggregate non-cleared positions with the cooperative are large,
encounter financial challenges. In this way, the credit risk of one of
the cooperative's counterparties could adversely impact the other
counterparties of that cooperative.
Conversely, if an exempt cooperative becomes insolvent and its
positions with a SD or MSP are substantial, it is possible that its
non-cleared positions could be large enough to exacerbate instability
at the SD or MSP or could create greater risk exposure for the members
with which the cooperative entered into swaps.
The FCC stated that because FCS institutions have collateral
agreements in place, ``clearing offers very little additional
protection to FCS institutions.'' The Commission acknowledges that
counterparty risk can be mitigated through collateral arrangements, but
also notes that the extent to which counterparty risk is reduced
through collateral agreements depends on the amount of collateral
required from each party to the swap, the liquidity of that collateral
in stressed market conditions, the frequency with which the amount of
collateral is adjusted to account for variations in the value of the
swap or the collateral, and the ability of the non-defaulting party to
claim the collateral quickly in the event that their counterparty
defaults.\80\ The Commission does not have adequate information to
determine how effectively collateral arrangements may mitigate
counterparty risk born by exempt cooperatives and their counterparties
in the absence of central clearing.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\80\ The 2012 ISDA Margin Survey indicates that 71% of all OTC
derivatives transactions were subject to collateral agreements
during 2011, but notes that the degree of collateralization may vary
significantly depending on the type of derivative and counterparties
entering into a transaction.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
3. Costs and Benefits for Other Market Participants
The ABA commented that the Commission did not consider competitive
harm to banks when analyzing the costs and benefits of the cooperative
exemption. The ABA and ICBA commented that cooperatives compete with
banks for the same business opportunities and provide similar services.
They further stated that the exemption would provide cooperatives with
a competitive advantage because they ``would have more liquidity
available for lending than comparable banks would and be able to
provide lower cost funding.'' Further, the ABA stated that ``the
competitive impact of the proposed exemption would grow as more
cooperatives increase their swaps portfolios to take advantage of the
pricing and other economic benefits it affords.''
The Commission recognizes that the cooperative exemption may
provide clearing cost savings related benefits to eligible cooperatives
with assets in excess of $10 billion.\81\ However, in assessing the
competitive costs and benefits of the cooperative exemption the
Commission believes the policy considerations for establishing
cooperatives also need to be taken into account. As described section
IV, Congress and the states have established the cooperative legal
structure distinct from other corporate forms to facilitate the
economic advantage of cooperative action for the mutual benefit of a
cooperative's members. The cooperative exemption provides the members
with the benefits of the end-user exception, both directly and
indirectly through their cooperatives, without having to switch from
doing business with their existing cooperatives to doing business with
small financial institutions or other entities that can elect to exempt
their swaps from clearing, but which are not organized for the specific
purpose of benefitting those members. The cooperative exemption
furthers these benefits by recognizing that the cooperatives were
established to act on behalf of their members in the marketplace and
providing an exemption from clearing to eligible cooperatives. In
effect, the cooperative exemption ensures that the existing members of
exempt cooperatives can achieve the full benefits of both cooperative
action and of the end-user exception.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\81\ The Commission notes, however, that most small banks are
also eligible for the end-user exception, which can be elected for a
wider range of swaps than the cooperative exemption. Section
50.50(d) of the Commission's regulations provides that banks, FCS
institutions, and credit unions that have total assets of $10
billion or less are eligible for the end-user exception with certain
exceptions--primarily that they not be SDs or MSPs.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
4. Costs and Benefits to the Public
The public generally has an interest in mandatory clearing because
of its potential to reduce counterparty risk among large,
interconnected institutions, and to facilitate rapid resolution of
outstanding positions held by such institutions in the event of their
default. By narrowly crafting the proposed cooperative exemption to
incorporate qualifying criteria limiting both the types of institutions
and the types of swaps that are eligible, the Commission has sought to
conserve this public interest.
The ABA and the ICBA commented that the four FCS banks and FCS
lending associations are jointly and severally liable for one another,
and that ``the aggregated asset size of these institutions is $230
billion and growing rapidly.'' The ICBA also stated that the financial
cooperatives affected by the exemption will grow larger over time and
may present a systemic risk in the future. The ABA stated that because
the FCS is a GSE, it is a potential liability to U.S. taxpayers. The
CUNA, on the other hand, asserted that the exemption would not have
significant impact on the overall swap market because of the small
number of entities eligible for the exemption. Similarly, the FCC
stated that because of collateral agreements that FCS institutions have
in place that ``the FCS poses no systemic risk to the U.S. financial
system.''
The Commission acknowledges that the magnitude of risk and
potential costs to the public created by an exemption from clearing
depends on several factors including: The number and size of the exempt
cooperatives electing the exemption; the size, number, and type of
exempt swaps held by each institution; the risks inherent in their
outstanding swaps; the concentration of swaps with individual
counterparties; the financial strength of counterparties to exempt
swaps; and the presence of collateral agreements related to the exempt
swaps.\82\ The Commission has limited data with which to evaluate these
factors. Commenters provided limited data, noting the size of the four
farm credit banks \83\ and the number and size of certain credit unions
with more than $10 billion in assets.\84\ However, commenters did not
provide, and the Commission does not have, detailed data regarding the
size of exempt cooperatives' non-cleared swaps, information regarding
the concentration
[[Page 52303]]
of non-cleared positions with particular counterparties, or information
regarding the financial strength of those counterparties. In addition,
while commenters noted the potential for collateral agreements to
mitigate counterparty risk in the absence of clearing, they did not
provide data or additional information regarding the agreements that
they anticipate will be used. Each of these factors could have a
significant bearing on how much risk is created for the public by
exempting eligible counterparties from the clearing requirement.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\82\ As noted above, the ability of collateral agreements to
mitigate counterparty risk and risk to the public depends on the
details of those agreements with regard to the amount and quality of
collateral required, the frequency with which it is adjusted to
reflect changing valuations, and the speed with which the non-
defaulting party can claim the collateral in the event that their
counterparty defaults.
\83\ ABA stated that the four Farm Credit banks have
approximately $15 billion, $29 billion, $76 billion, and $90 billion
in assets.
\84\ ABA stated that there are four credit unions with more than
$10 billion in assets and are likely to be several more within the
next year. They also stated that one credit union has nearly $50
billion in assets and another has more than $25 billion.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Notwithstanding the limited data available, the Commission
considered the potential risks that could arise from cooperatives
entering into non-cleared swaps and the Commission believes it has
mitigated these risks with the conditions imposed in the rule that
limit the number of entities and types of swaps eligible for the
cooperative exemption. These conditions are described in sections I, II
and II above.
In addition, the Commission notes that cooperatives that may
qualify as exempt cooperatives are supervised by other regulators that
have access to more detailed information regarding the swaps executed
by the cooperatives and that are likely to have additional information
regarding the risk factors discussed above. These regulators can
monitor the use of swaps by these cooperatives and the risk factors
related to that swap activity. Using this information, these regulators
can assess the risks related to the non-cleared swaps in the context of
the overall regulatory framework applicable to the cooperatives and the
changing financial condition of the cooperatives and in that context
address the potential systemic risk with the cooperatives using their
regulatory authority.
Finally, while it is important to consider the potential risks
noted above, it is also important to assess the benefits provided by
the cooperative exemption. The Commission believes ensuring that the
members of exempt cooperatives can continue to use their cooperatives
in the manner intended and also realize the full benefits of the end-
user exception through their cooperatives is appropriate given the
unique nature of cooperatives and the statutory and policy
considerations discussed above in section III.
D. Costs and Benefits Compared to Alternatives
There were several alternatives proposed by commenters that the
Commission considered including: Providing a ``ride along'' exemption
for community banks larger than $10 billion; and including cooperatives
with members that are financial entities, either with or without
additional restrictions on the eligibility of swaps conducted by such
cooperatives.
The Commission considered a ``ride-along'' provision, proposed by
the ICBA, which would provide a clearing exemption for community banks
that exceed the $10 billion total assets threshold. Providing a ``ride-
along'' provision could mitigate the potential competitive effects of
the exception, as alleged by the ICBA, but would also increase the
potential risk to the public by increasing the number of large
financial entities eligible for an exemption from clearing.
Moreover, expanding the exemption in this way could also make it
possible for SDs, MSPs, and other large financial institutions to avoid
clearing by using exempt community banks as an intermediary for their
swap transactions. Finally, allowing non-cooperatives to use the
exemption would not reflect the unique structure of cooperatives that
is the basis for the exemption and result in an expansion of the small
financial institution exemption beyond the parameters detailed in the
final release for the Commissions regulations implementing the end-user
exception.\85\ For these reasons, the Commission has determined not to
include the suggested ``ride-along'' provision.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\85\ 77 FR 42559 (Jul. 19, 2012).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The ICBA also stated that the cooperative exemption does not
include the FHL Banks, and that thousands of small banks that are
members of the FHL Bank system will be disadvantaged by the cooperative
exemption because the FHL Banks will not be able to provide the same or
similar low cost financing to community banks as FCS lenders do for
their cooperative associations. The ICBA and the FHL Banks commented
that the FHL Banks should be included as exempt cooperatives either
generally, or to the extent they provide services to their members that
qualify for the small financial institution exemption from the
definition of financial entity.
In the NPRM, the Commission considered including cooperatives
consisting of members that could not elect the end-user exception, as
suggested by the FHL Banks. Such an exemption would assist in ensuring
that a greater number of cooperatives are able to elect not to clear
swaps. However, as described in greater detail in section III, if the
cooperatives elected the exemption when transacting with or for the
benefit of members that are not eligible for the end-user exception
(i.e. financial institutions with total assets greater than $10
billion) it could significantly increase the number of swaps that are
exempt from the clearing requirement and result in exemptions for
entities that Congress has not provided any indication should be exempt
from the clearing requirement.\86\ If the cooperative exemption were
expanded in this way, it would reduce the benefits derived from
required clearing. By contrast, with the limiting conditions included
in the cooperative exemption rule, the Commission is ensuring that the
exemption is only available to cooperatives whose members can elect the
end-user exception or are themselves cooperatives whose members can
elect the end-user exception.\87\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\86\ Note, for example, that while the FHL Banks have thousands
of members that qualify for the small financial institution
exemption and who therefor can elect the end-user exception, over
one hundred members of the FHL Banks would not qualify because they
are financial entities with total assets in excess of $10 billion.
These members include some of the largest financial entities in the
United States. In addition, as described above in section III,
financial entities with assets in excess of $10 billion have
borrowed more than half the amount lent by the FHL banks to members.
\87\ The Commission notes that banks and other entities that
qualify for the small financial institution exemption from the
financial entity definition are not excluded under the regulation
from being members of exempt cooperatives.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The FHL Banks suggested that this problem could be addressed by
limiting the exemption to swaps that hedge risks associated with loans
to eligible members. However, allowing new or existing cooperatives
with financial entity members to elect not to clear swaps related to
activities with members that are eligible for the end-user exception
would dilute the benefits that qualifying members achieve through the
exemption thereby undermining the purpose for the exemption. For
example, as described above in section III, if the FHL Banks elect the
cooperative exemption only for swaps related to members who qualify as
small financial institutions, the decision not to clear those swaps
could create clearing cost savings for the FHL Banks. Those savings
would increase the capital that the FHL Banks distribute or allocate to
their members as part of the full member pro rata patronage
distribution. If larger members hold a large ownership stake in the
cooperative, those members would also receive a proportionately large
share of the distributions, including a proportionately large share of
the savings that result from the cooperative
[[Page 52304]]
exemption.\88\ In other words, members that are eligible for the end-
user exception would not receive the full benefits of the exemption
that is extended to the cooperative. By contrast, with the limiting
conditions included in the cooperative exemption rule, the Commission
is ensuring that the exemption is only available to cooperatives whose
members could all elect the end-user exception or are themselves
cooperatives whose members could elect the end-user exception, and thus
the additional pro-rata patronage distributions that an exempt
cooperative makes because of the cooperative exemption will only go to
such entities.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\88\ See section II above for a full discussion of the relative
benefits available to different sized members of the FHL Banks.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The FCC requested clarification with respect to the Commission's
view on what swaps are ``related to'' a cooperative's loans to its
members, and advocated a broad interpretation. They also stated that
``clarification of these items will serve to increase the likelihood
that the System's farmer and rancher member borrowers will be able to
benefit from this proposed exemption from clearing.'' The broader
interpretation requested by the FCC could increase the number of swaps
that are eligible for the exemption by including swaps that serve non-
member related purposes, which would further reduce clearing-related
costs for eligible cooperatives, but would also increase the
counterparty risk that eligible cooperatives and their counterparties
bear due to decreased clearing. In the Commission's view, this broader
exemption is not justified given the rationale behind the cooperative
exemption. As stated above, the term ``related to'' is intended to
include swaps that the exempt cooperatives may enter into with non-
members to hedge or mitigate the risks incurred by the cooperatives
related to their member lending activities. For example, where
cooperatives obtain wholesale funding, only the portion of funding that
is not used to make non-member loans may be hedged with exempt
swaps.\89\ By limiting the eligibility of exempt cooperatives' swaps in
this way, the Commission reduces the counterparty risk that exempt
cooperatives and their counterparties could experience due to decreased
clearing.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\89\ See section III.C above.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
E. Section 15(a) Factors
1. Protection of Market Participants and the Public
As described above, if exempt cooperatives elect to exempt certain
swaps from required clearing, these cooperatives may not need to pay
DCO and FCM clearing fees for clearing those swaps. In addition, the
exemption may reduce the amount of capital that exempt cooperatives
must allocate to margin accounts with their FCM. This, in turn,
provides benefits to the members of exempt cooperatives, that may
otherwise absorb such costs as they are passed on by the cooperatives
to their members in the form of fees, less desirable spreads on swaps
or loans conducted with the cooperative, or lower member allocated
capital or patronage distributions.
The exemption will create certain reporting costs for eligible
entities. However, as described in the rulemaking for the end-user
exception where the specific reporting requirements were addressed, the
reporting required uses a simple check-the-box approach and elective
annual reporting of certain information that should minimize per swap
reporting costs, particularly for cooperatives that enter into multiple
swaps.
The exemption is narrowly tailored to exempt only a relatively
small number of institutions and to include only swaps that are
associated with positions established in connection with originating
loans made to customers, or that hedge or mitigate risk arising in
connection with such member loans or swaps. These limitations will tend
to mitigate the risk to the public that could result from the
exemption.
In addition, this exemption is likely to increase counterparty risk
for counterparties to exempted swaps as well as for the exempted
cooperatives. However, as described above, exempted cooperatives and
their counterparties may use collateral agreements with exempted swaps
to mitigate counterparty risk.
2. Efficiency, Competitiveness, and Financial Integrity of Swap Markets
While the cooperative exemption would take swaps out of clearing,
it mitigates the impact on the financial integrity of the swap markets
by limiting the types of entities and swaps that are eligible. As
discussed above, the exemption is designed to include only cooperatives
that are made up entirely of entities that could elect the end-user
exception, and only swaps associated with loans between the cooperative
and such members.
The exemption may have competitive effects by allowing the members
of exempt cooperatives to achieve additional benefits from the actions
of their cooperatives. The Commission believes such benefits are
consistent with the intended public interests served by the
establishment of cooperative structures as a separate legal form by
Congress and the states. The Commission addresses these issues in
section IV and VI.C.3. Commenters did not provide, and the Commission
does not have, information that is sufficient to quantify the
competitive effects that will result from the exemption.
3. Price Discovery
Clearing, in general, encourages better price discovery because it
eliminates the importance of counterparty creditworthiness in pricing
swaps cleared through a given DCO. That is, by making the counterparty
creditworthiness of all swaps of a certain type essentially the same,
prices should reflect factors related to the terms of the swap, rather
than the idiosyncratic risk posed by the entities trading it.\90\ To
the extent that the cooperative exemption reduces the number of swaps
subject to required clearing, it will lessen the beneficial effects of
required clearing for price discovery. However, the Commission
anticipates that the number of swaps eligible for this exemption,
currently estimated at approximately 500 a year, will be a de minimis
fraction of all those that are otherwise required to be cleared.
Therefore, the Commission believes that there will not be a material
impact on price discovery.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\90\ See Chen, K., et al. ``An Analysis of CDS Transactions:
Implications for Public Reporting,'' September 2011, Federal Reserve
Bank of New York Staff Reports, at 14.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
4. Sound Risk Management Practices
To the extent that a swap is removed from clearing, all other
things being constant, it is a detriment to a sound risk management
regime. To the extent that exempt cooperatives enter into non-cleared
swaps on the basis of this rule, it likely increases the exposure of
exempt cooperatives and their counterparties to counterparty credit
risk. For the public, it increases the risk that financial distress at
one or more cooperatives could spread to other financial institutions
with which those cooperatives have concentrated positions. However, as
discussed above, this additional risk may be reduced by the presence of
bilateral margin agreements, which the Commission
[[Page 52305]]
believes are often used in the absence of clearing.
5. Other Public Interest Considerations
The Commission believes that the cooperative exemption serves the
public interest by furthering the public benefits cited by Congress and
state legislatures in legislation authorizing cooperative business
forms as discussed in section IV above. The cooperative structure
allows the members to pool their resources, achieve economies of scale,
and realize the benefits of acting in markets through larger entities.
However, absent the cooperative exemption, the exempt cooperatives
would be unable to elect the end-user exception because the amount of
their assets precludes them from qualifying as small financial
institutions. In effect, the cooperative structure, which is intended
to provide advantages to its member-owners by creating a large entity
whose mission is to serve their interests, instead prevents the members
from receiving the full benefits of the end-user exception when using
their large cooperatives. The cooperative exemption therefor is in the
public interest because it resolves a conflict between the small
financial institution language of section 2(h)(7) of the CEA and the
general policy behind establishing cooperatives of creating large
financial institutions with the mission of serving the mutual interests
of their member-owners.
VII. Related Matters
A. Regulatory Flexibility Act
The Regulatory Flexibility Act (``RFA'') requires that agencies
consider whether the rules they propose will have a significant
economic impact on a substantial number of small entities \91\ and, if
so, provide a regulatory flexibility analysis respecting the
impact.\92\ Regulation Sec. 39.6(f) (now Sec. 50.51) would affect
cooperatives, their members, and potentially the counterparties with
whom they trade. These entities could be SDs, MSPs, and eligible
contract participants (``ECPs'').\93\ Regulation Sec. 39.6(f) (now
Sec. 50.51) would additionally affect SDRs. As noted in the NPRM, the
Commission has previously determined that SDs, MSPs, and SDRs are not
small entities for purposes of the RFA.\94\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\91\ The Small Business Administration identifies (by North
American Industry Classification System codes) a small business size
standard of $7 million or less in annual receipts for Subsector
523--Securities, Commodity Contracts, and Other Financial
Investments and Related Activities. 13 CFR parts 1, 121.201.
\92\ 5 U.S.C. 601 et seq.
\93\ It is possible that a cooperative or members thereof may
not be ECPs. However, pursuant to Section 2(e) of the CEA, if a
counterparty to a swap is not an ECP, then such swap must be entered
into on, or subject to the rules of, a board of trade designated as
a contract market under Section 5 of the CEA. All such swaps must be
cleared by the board of trade. See section 5(d)(11) of the CEA, 7
U.S.C. 7(d)(11). In effect all swaps entered into by a cooperative
or a member that is not an ECP will need to be executed on a board
of trade and therefore will be cleared.
\94\ See 77 FR 30596, 30701 (May 23, 2012); see also 75 FR
80898, 80926 (Dec. 23, 2010).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
It is possible that some members of cooperatives may be small
entities under the RFA. For these members to be impacted by the
cooperative exemption compliance requirements they would have to be
entering into swaps with the exempt cooperative and the exemption would
need to be elected. In order for two counterparties to a swap to enter
into a swap bilaterally, both parties must be ECPs.\95\ Based on the
definition of ECP in the Commodity Futures Modernization Act of 2000,
and the legislative history underlying that definition, the Commission
has previously determined that ECPs should not be small entities for
purposes of the RFA.\96\ The Commission has been made aware in other
contexts that some ECPs, specifically those that do not fall within a
category of ECP that is subject to a dollar threshold, may be small
entities. If there are cooperative members that are both ECPs as
defined in the CEA and small entities for purposes of the RFA, the
exemption is nevertheless most likely to provide an economic benefit to
the cooperative member. Furthermore, if elected, the cooperative
exemption would impose the same or similar costs of compliance on
members that the previously adopted end-user exception from the
clearing requirement imposes. The end-user exception provides
effectively the same type of relief from clearing. Accordingly, the
cooperative exemption does not create any materially new or different
compliance costs than similar regulations that were previously adopted.
Finally, the cooperative exemption is elective. If a member that is a
small entity wanted to clear its swap, the cooperative exemption does
not require them to enter into swaps with their cooperatives and they
could execute swaps with other parties that would agree to clearing.
Accordingly, the cooperative exemption would not cause any new
significant economic impact on these members.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\95\ 7 U.S.C. 2(e).
\96\ See 66 FR 20740, 20743 (Apr. 25, 2001).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The Chairman, on behalf of the Commission, certified in the NPRM,
pursuant to 5 U.S.C. 605(b), that Sec. 39.6(f) (now Sec. 50.51(a))
will not have a significant impact on a substantial number of small
entities. The Commission requested comment on this decision in the
NPRM.
The ICBA commented that the proposal impacts a substantial number
of small community banks because they are members of the FHL banks and
the FHL banks are not exempt cooperatives. According to the ICBA, the
small bank members of the FHL bank system would be disadvantaged
because the FHL banks will not be able to provide the same or similar
low cost financing to community banks as FCS lenders will for their
cooperatives.
The Commission also received two comments regarding the impact of
Regulation Sec. 39.6(f) (now Sec. 50.51(a)) on the competition
between banks that are small entities and cooperatives that elect the
cooperative exemption. According to the ABA, the Commission's analysis
of the economic impact on small entities did not consider that economic
impact on the ``hundreds of end-user banks that are competing with
cooperatives for the same business opportunities.'' Similarly, the ICBA
commented that the ``competitive advantages afforded to large credit
unions and large FCS funding banks . . . would allow these institutions
advantages in competing directly against small community banks even if
they have a small financial institution exemption.'' The ICBA then
referenced CoBank as an example of an FCS funding bank with a wide
geographic footprint over two dozen states that could grow larger.
The ABA and the ICBA asserted that the Commission is obliged under
the RFA to consider the impact of the regulation on small banks,
including small banks that are members of the FHL bank system.
Specifically, commenters asserted that the Commission should consider
the competitive benefit the cooperative exemption might give to exempt
cooperatives as compared to small banks that might be small entities
for purposes of the RFA both on their own and because small banks are
members of the FHL bank system.\97\ The Commission has applied the RFA
to entities that are cooperatives who may elect the cooperative
exemption and their members. Small community banks that are not members
of exempt cooperatives are not subject to the cooperative exemption.
The Commission also notes that, as discussed above, to the extent a
small
[[Page 52306]]
community bank is or becomes a member of an exempt cooperative and
enters into a swap bilaterally with an exempt cooperative for which the
cooperative exemption is elected, that member would have to be an ECP,
in order to enter into the swap bilaterally, and also an entity that
could elect the end-user exception. Accordingly, the Commission
continues to believe that the cooperative exemption will not have a
significant economic impact on small entities.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\97\ The FHL banks would not qualify for the cooperative
exemption because they have large financial entity members. See
section IV above.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Therefore, the Chairman, on behalf of the Commission, hereby
certifies, pursuant to 5 U.S.C. 605(b), that the final regulation would
not have a significant economic impact on a substantial number of small
entities.
B. Paperwork Reduction Act
Regulation Sec. 39.6(f)(3) (now Sec. 50.51(c)) requires a
cooperative to conform with certain reporting conditions if it elects
the cooperative exemption. These new requirements constitute a
collection of information within the meaning of the Paperwork Reduction
Act of 1995 (``PRA'').\98\ Under the PRA, an agency may not conduct or
sponsor, and a person is not required to respond to, a collection of
information unless it has been approved by the Office of Management and
Budget (``OMB'') and displays a currently valid control number.\99\
This rulemaking contains new collections of information for which the
Commission must seek a valid control number. The Commission therefore
requested that OMB assign a control number and OMB assigned control
number 3038-0102 for this new collection of information. The Commission
has also submitted the proposed rulemaking, this final rule release,
and supporting documentation to OMB for review in accordance with 44
U.S.C. 3507(d) and 5 CFR 1320.11. The title for these new collections
of information is ``Rule 39.6(f) Cooperative Clearing Exemption
Notification.'' Responses to these information collections will be
mandatory if the cooperative exemption is elected.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\98\ 44 U.S.C. 3501 et seq.
\99\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
With respect to all of the Commission's collections, the Commission
will protect proprietary information according to the Freedom of
Information Act and 17 CFR part 145, ``Commission Records and
Information.'' In addition, section 8(a)(1) of the Act strictly
prohibits the Commission, unless specifically authorized by the Act,
from making public ``data and information that would separately
disclose the business transactions or market positions of any person
and trade secrets or names of customers.'' The Commission also is
required to protect certain information contained in a government
system of records according to the Privacy Act of 1974, 5 U.S.C. 552a.
1. Information To Be Provided by Reporting Parties
For each swap where the exemption is elected, either the
cooperative, or its counterparty if the counterparty is an SD or MSP,
must report: (1) That the election of the exemption is being made; (2)
which party is the electing counterparty; and (3) certain information
specific to the electing counterparty unless that information has
already been provided by the electing counterparty through an annual
filing. As noted in the NPRM, the third set of information comprises
data that is likely to remain relatively constant for many, but not
all, electing counterparties and therefore, does not require swap-by-
swap reporting and can be reported less frequently. In addition, for
entities registered with the SEC, the reporting party will also be
required to report: (1) The SEC filer's central index key number; and
(2) that an appropriate committee of the board of directors has
approved the decision for that entity to enter into swaps that are
exempt from the requirements of section 2(h)(1)(A) of the CEA.
Exempt cooperatives entering into swaps with members and electing
the exemption will likely be responsible to report this information.
When cooperatives enter into swaps with SDs or MSPs, the SDs or MSPs
will be responsible for reporting the information, but cooperatives
would bear some costs related to the personnel hours committed to
reporting the required information.
As discussed in the NPRM, for purposes of estimating the cost of
reporting in connection with the cooperative exemption, the Commission
estimated that each of the ten exempt cooperatives would enter into 50
swaps per year on average. Accordingly, the Commission estimated that
exempt cooperatives would elect the cooperative exemption for 500 swaps
each year. The reporting cost estimates are discussed separately below
according to each requirement.
The Commission invited public comment on any aspect of the
reporting burdens discussed in the NPRM. The Commission received two
comments on the Commission's approach to calculating the estimated cost
burdens. The ABA questioned whether the Commission had underestimated
its estimations of the number of cooperatives eligible for the
exemption, and the number of swaps each eligible cooperative engages in
per year. The ABA also commented that the figures used are static and
as such do not allow for potential future growth in the number of
potential exempt cooperatives and number of swaps in which they may
transact. The ICBA similarly commented on the static nature
Commission's approach, and noted that the approach does not account for
future growth when the use of swaps in the OTC market has grown
significantly in recent years. Furthermore, the ICBA noted that the
CFTC looked at information from five of the ten estimated cooperatives
that may be eligible for the cooperative exemption, but did not
indicate which of the five cooperatives it considered or what the
reason was for not reviewing information from the other five
cooperatives.
In response to the comments received, the Commission notes that the
commenters provided no data or other information to support their
assertions that the number of cooperatives and the number of swaps that
may be eligible for the cooperative exemption may be low or inaccurate.
The summary information regarding swap activities of five prospective
exempt cooperatives was provided to the Commission on a voluntary basis
through the FCC and CFC. Based on discussions with these entities, the
Commission believes that these five cooperatives were more active than
the other potential exempt cooperatives in using swaps and therefore
this sampling of information was appropriate for estimating the number
of swaps executed by the ten potential exempt cooperatives identified
by the Commission. Subsequent to receipt of the comments on the NPRM,
the Commission contacted the regulators for FCS cooperatives and
federal credit unions and these regulators expressed a view that the
Commission's estimates were not inappropriate.
In response to the comments that the estimates represent only a
current snap shot of activity, the Commission recognizes that the
number of entities eligible for the exemption and the number of swaps
per eligible cooperative is likely to change in the future and that the
benefits of this exemption for exempt cooperatives could encourage more
exempt cooperatives to use swaps and could increase the number of swaps
used by those cooperatives. However, the Commission notes that whether
such growth is realized also depends on
[[Page 52307]]
additional factors that the Commission does not have adequate
information to evaluate such as: (1) Subsequent changes to laws or
regulations affecting one or more types of cooperatives and the extent
to which they may use swaps; (2) increases or decreases in the total
amount of borrowing undertaken by the members of those cooperatives;
and (3) the frequency with which exempt cooperatives make the types of
loans or experience other business changes that might increase or
decrease the use of swaps. It is not possible to evaluate how future
changes in these factors are likely to affect the number of swaps for
which the cooperative exemption may be elected. Accordingly, the
Commission believes using a static estimate is reasonable.
a. Regulation Sec. 39.6(f)(3) (now Sec. 50.51(c)): Reporting
Requirements
Regulation Sec. 39.6(f)(3) (now Sec. 50.51(c)) requires exempt
cooperatives that are reporting counterparties to comply with the
reporting requirements of Sec. 50.50(b), which require delivering
specific information to a registered SDR or, if no SDR is available,
the Commission. An exempt cooperative that is the reporting
counterparty would have to report the information required in Sec.
50.50(b)(1)(i) and (ii) for each swap for which it elects the
cooperative exemption.
As discussed in the NPRM, the Commission anticipates that to comply
with Sec. 50.50(b)(1)(i) and (ii), each reporting counterparty would
be required to check one box in the SDR or Commission reporting data
fields indicating that the exempt cooperative is electing not to clear
the swap. The Commission estimated that the cost of complying with this
requirement for each reporting counterparty to be between less than $1
and $7 for each transaction, or approximately $300 to $3,500 per year
for all transactions.
The Commission did not receive any comments concerning the cost to
exempt cooperatives from complying with Sec. 50.50(b)(1)(i) and (ii).
b. Regulation Sec. 50.50(b)(1)(iii): Annual Reporting Option
Regulation 50.50(b)(1)(iii) allows for certain counterparty
specific information identified therein to be reported either swap-by-
swap by the reporting counterparty or annually by the electing
counterparty. As discussed in the NPRM, the Commission anticipates that
the exempt cooperatives will make annual filings of the information
required. The Commission estimated the annual per cooperative cost for
the filing to be between $200 and $590, or $2,000 to $5,900 as the
aggregate cost for all exempt cooperatives.
The Commission did not receive any comments concerning the cost to
exempt cooperatives for electing the annual reporting option under
Sec. 50.50(b)(1)(iii).
c. Updating Reporting Procedures
As discussed in the NPRM, the Commission anticipates that
cooperatives electing the exemption that are reporting counterparties
may need to modify their reporting systems to accommodate the
additional data fields required by the rule. The Commission estimated
that the modifications to comply with Sec. 39.6(f)(3) (now Sec.
50.51(c)) would likely cost each reporting counterparty between $340
and $3,400, with the aggregate one-time cost for all potential exempt
cooperatives to be $3,400 to $34,100.
The Commission did not receive any comments concerning the cost to
exempt cooperatives in updating their reporting systems to comply with
Sec. 39.6(f)(3) (now Sec. 50.51(c)).
d. Burden on Non-Reporting Cooperatives
As discussed in the NPRM, when an exempt cooperative is not
functioning as the reporting counterparty (i.e., when transacting with
an SD or MSP), the Commission anticipated that it may, at certain
times, need to communicate information to its reporting counterparties
in order to facilitate reporting. This information might include
whether the exempt cooperative has filed an annual report pursuant to
Sec. 50.50(b), and information to facilitate any due diligence that
the reporting counterparty may conduct. The Commission estimated that a
non-reporting exempt cooperative would incur an annual aggregate cost
for communicating information to the reporting counterparty between
$400 and $39,000.\100\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\100\ The Commission noted the wide range in this estimation,
but explained the range could not be narrowed given the unknowns
associated with the cost estimate.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The Commission did not receive any comments concerning the cost a
non-reporting exempt cooperative will incur in communicating
information to the reporting counterparty.
List of Subjects in 17 CFR Part 50
Business and industry, Clearing, Cooperatives, Reporting
requirements, Swaps.
Accordingly, the CFTC amends 17 CFR part 50 as follows:
PART 50--CLEARING REQUIREMENT AND RELATED RULES
0
1. The authority citation for part 50 continues to read as follows:
Authority: 7 U.S.C. 2 and 7a-1 as amended by Pub. L. 111-203,
124 Stat. 1376.
0
2. Add Sec. 50.51 to read as follows:
Sec. 50.51 Exemption for Cooperatives.
Exemption for cooperatives. Exempt cooperatives may elect not to
clear certain swaps identified in paragraph (b) of this section that
are otherwise subject to the clearing requirement of section 2(h)(1)(A)
of the Act if the following requirements are satisfied.
(a) For the purposes of this paragraph, an exempt cooperative means
a cooperative:
(1) Formed and existing pursuant to Federal or state law as a
cooperative;
(2) That is a ``financial entity,'' as defined in section
2(h)(7)(C)(i) of the Act, solely because of section 2(h)(7)(C)(i)(VIII)
of the Act; and
(3) Each member of which is not a ``financial entity,'' as defined
in section 2(h)(7)(C)(i) of the Act, or if any member is a financial
entity solely because of section 2(h)(7)(C)(i)(VIII) of the Act, such
member is:
(i) Exempt from the definition of ``financial entity'' pursuant to
Sec. 50.50(d); or
(ii) A cooperative formed under Federal or state law as a
cooperative and each member thereof is either not a ``financial
entity,'' as defined in section 2(h)(7)(C)(i) of the Act, or is exempt
from the definition of ``financial entity'' pursuant to Sec. 50.50(d).
(b) An exempt cooperative may elect not to clear a swap that is
subject to the clearing requirement of section 2(h)(1)(A) of the Act if
the swap:
(1) Is entered into with a member of the exempt cooperative in
connection with originating a loan or loans for the member, which means
the requirements of Sec. 1.3(ggg)(5)(i), (ii), and (iii) are
satisfied; provided that, for this purpose, the term ``insured
depository institution'' as used in those sections is replaced with the
term ``exempt cooperative'' and the word ``customer'' is replaced with
the word ``member;'' or
(2) Hedges or mitigates commercial risk, in accordance with Sec.
50.50(c), related to loans to members or arising from a swap or swaps
that meet the requirements of paragraph (b)(1) of this section.
(c) An exempt cooperative that elects the exemption provided in
this section shall comply with the requirements of Sec. 50.50(b). For
this purpose, the exempt cooperative shall be the ``electing
[[Page 52308]]
counterparty,'' as such term is used in Sec. 50.50(b), and for
purposes of Sec. 50.50(b)(1)(iii)(A), the reporting counterparty, as
determined pursuant to Sec. 45.8, shall report that an exemption is
being elected in accordance with this section.
Issued in Washington, DC, on August 13, 2013, by the Commission.
Melissa D. Jurgens,
Secretary of the Commission.
Note: The following appendix will not appear in the Code of
Federal Regulations.
Appendix to Clearing Exemption for Certain Swaps Entered Into by
Cooperatives--Commission Voting Summary
Appendix 1--Commission Voting Summary
On this matter, Chairman Gensler and Commissioners Chilton,
O'Malia, and Wetjen voted in the affirmative.
[FR Doc. 2013-19945 Filed 8-21-13; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6351-01-P