Graco, Inc.; Analysis of Agreement Containing Consent Order To Aid Public Comment, 24201-24206 [2013-09673]
Download as PDF
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 79 / Wednesday, April 24, 2013 / Notices
President) 1 Memorial Drive, Kansas
City, Missouri 64198–0001:
1. Goering Management Company,
L.L.C. and Goering Financial Holding
Company Partnership, L.P., both in
Moundridge, Kansas; to retain at least
43 percent of the voting shares of Bon,
Inc., Moundridge, Kansas, and thereby
indirectly retain voting shares of Home
State Bank & Trust Co., McPherson,
Kansas, and The Citizens State Bank,
Moundridge, Kansas.
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System, April 19, 2013.
Margaret McCloskey Shanks,
Deputy Secretary of the Board.
[FR Doc. 2013–09641 Filed 4–23–13; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6210–01–P
FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION
[File No. 101 0215]
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System, April 19, 2013.
Margaret McCloskey Shanks,
Deputy Secretary of the Board.
Graco, Inc.; Analysis of Agreement
Containing Consent Order To Aid
Public Comment
[FR Doc. 2013–09642 Filed 4–23–13; 8:45 am]
AGENCY:
BILLING CODE 6210–01–P
ACTION:
Federal Trade Commission.
Proposed Consent Agreement.
The consent agreement in this
matter settles alleged violations of
federal law prohibiting unfair or
deceptive acts or practices or unfair
methods of competition. The attached
Analysis to Aid Public Comment
describes both the allegations in the
draft complaint and the terms of the
consent order—embodied in the consent
agreement—that would settle these
allegations.
SUMMARY:
FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM
tkelley on DSK3SPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
Notice of Proposals To Engage in or
To Acquire Companies Engaged in
Permissible Nonbanking Activities
The companies listed in this notice
have given notice under section 4 of the
Bank Holding Company Act (12 U.S.C.
1843) (BHC Act) and Regulation Y, (12
CFR part 225) to engage de novo, or to
acquire or control voting securities or
assets of a company, including the
companies listed below, that engages
either directly or through a subsidiary or
other company, in a nonbanking activity
that is listed in § 225.28 of Regulation Y
(12 CFR 225.28) or that the Board has
determined by Order to be closely
related to banking and permissible for
bank holding companies. Unless
otherwise noted, these activities will be
conducted throughout the United States.
Each notice is available for inspection
at the Federal Reserve Bank indicated.
The notice also will be available for
inspection at the offices of the Board of
Governors. Interested persons may
express their views in writing on the
question whether the proposal complies
with the standards of section 4 of the
BHC Act.
Unless otherwise noted, comments
regarding the applications must be
received at the Reserve Bank indicated
or the offices of the Board of Governors
not later than May 9, 2013.
A. Federal Reserve Bank of San
Francisco (Gerald C. Tsai, Director,
Applications and Enforcement) 101
Market Street, San Francisco, California
94105–1579:
1. One PacificCoast Foundation,
Oakland, California; to engage de novo
in community development activities
and nonbanking activities incidental to
extending credit, pursuant to sections
225.28(b)(12)(i) and 225.28(b)(2)(i),
respectively.
VerDate Mar<15>2010
18:05 Apr 23, 2013
Jkt 229001
Comments must be received on
or before May 20, 2013.
ADDRESSES: Interested parties may file a
comment at https://
ftcpublic.commentworks.com/ftc/
gracoconsent online or on paper, by
following the instructions in the
Request for Comment part of the
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION section
below. Write ‘‘Graco, File No. 101 0215’’
on your comment and file your
comment online at https://
ftcpublic.commentworks.com/ftc/
gracoconsent by following the
instructions on the web-based form. If
you prefer to file your comment on
paper, mail or deliver your comment to
the following address: Federal Trade
Commission, Office of the Secretary,
Room H–113 (Annex D), 600
Pennsylvania Avenue NW., Washington,
DC 20580.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
Benjamin Jackson (202–326–2193), FTC,
Bureau of Competition, 600
Pennsylvania Avenue NW., Washington,
DC 20580.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: Pursuant
to Section 6(f) of the Federal Trade
Commission Act, 15 U.S.C. 46(f), and
FTC Rule 2.34, 16 CFR 2.34, notice is
hereby given that the above-captioned
consent agreement containing a consent
order to cease and desist, having been
filed with and accepted, subject to final
approval, by the Commission, has been
placed on the public record for a period
DATES:
PO 00000
Frm 00052
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
24201
of thirty (30) days. The following
Analysis to Aid Public Comment
describes the terms of the consent
agreement, and the allegations in the
complaint. An electronic copy of the
full text of the consent agreement
package can be obtained from the FTC
Home Page (for April 18, 2013), on the
World Wide Web, at https://www.ftc.gov/
os/actions.shtm. A paper copy can be
obtained from the FTC Public Reference
Room, Room 130–H, 600 Pennsylvania
Avenue NW., Washington, DC 20580,
either in person or by calling (202) 326–
2222.
You can file a comment online or on
paper. For the Commission to consider
your comment, we must receive it on or
before May 20, 2013. Write ‘‘Graco, File
No. 101 0215’’ on your comment. Your
comment—including your name and
your state—will be placed on the public
record of this proceeding, including, to
the extent practicable, on the public
Commission Web site, at https://
www.ftc.gov/os/publiccomments.shtm.
As a matter of discretion, the
Commission tries to remove individuals’
home contact information from
comments before placing them on the
Commission Web site.
Because your comment will be made
public, you are solely responsible for
making sure that your comment does
not include any sensitive personal
information, like anyone’s Social
Security number, date of birth, driver’s
license number or other state
identification number or foreign country
equivalent, passport number, financial
account number, or credit or debit card
number. You are also solely responsible
for making sure that your comment does
not include any sensitive health
information, like medical records or
other individually identifiable health
information. In addition, do not include
any ‘‘[t]rade secret or any commercial or
financial information which * * * is
privileged or confidential,’’ as discussed
in Section 6(f) of the FTC Act, 15 U.S.C.
46(f), and FTC Rule 4.10(a)(2), 16 CFR
4.10(a)(2). In particular, do not include
competitively sensitive information
such as costs, sales statistics,
inventories, formulas, patterns, devices,
manufacturing processes, or customer
names.
If you want the Commission to give
your comment confidential treatment,
you must file it in paper form, with a
request for confidential treatment, and
you have to follow the procedure
explained in FTC Rule 4.9(c), 16 CFR
4.9(c).1 Your comment will be kept
1 In particular, the written request for confidential
treatment that accompanies the comment must
E:\FR\FM\24APN1.SGM
Continued
24APN1
24202
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 79 / Wednesday, April 24, 2013 / Notices
confidential only if the FTC General
Counsel, in his or her sole discretion,
grants your request in accordance with
the law and the public interest.
Postal mail addressed to the
Commission is subject to delay due to
heightened security screening. As a
result, we encourage you to submit your
comments online. To make sure that the
Commission considers your online
comment, you must file it at https://
ftcpublic.commentworks.com/ftc/
gracoconsent by following the
instructions on the web-based form. If
this Notice appears at https://
www.regulations.gov/#!home, you also
may file a comment through that Web
site.
If you file your comment on paper,
write ‘‘Graco, File No. 101 0215’’ on
your comment and on the envelope, and
mail or deliver it to the following
address: Federal Trade Commission,
Office of the Secretary, Room H–113
(Annex D), 600 Pennsylvania Avenue
NW., Washington, DC 20580. If possible,
submit your paper comment to the
Commission by courier or overnight
service.
Visit the Commission Web site at
https://www.ftc.gov to read this Notice
and the news release describing it. The
FTC Act and other laws that the
Commission administers permit the
collection of public comments to
consider and use in this proceeding as
appropriate. The Commission will
consider all timely and responsive
public comments that it receives on or
before May 20, 2013. You can find more
information, including routine uses
permitted by the Privacy Act, in the
Commission’s privacy policy, at https://
www.ftc.gov/ftc/privacy.htm.
tkelley on DSK3SPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
Analysis of Agreement Containing
Consent Order To Aid Public Comment
The Federal Trade Commission
(‘‘Commission’’) has accepted for public
comment an Agreement Containing
Consent Order (‘‘Consent Order’’) with
Graco, Inc. (‘‘Graco’’) to remedy the
alleged anticompetitive effects resulting
from Graco’s acquisition of its most
significant competitors, Gusmer Corp.
(‘‘Gusmer’’) and GlasCraft, Inc.
(‘‘GlasCraft’’). The Commission
Complaint (‘‘Complaint’’) alleges that, at
the time of the acquisitions, Graco,
Gusmer, and GlasCraft each
manufactured and sold equipment for
the application of fast-set chemicals
(‘‘fast-set equipment’’). Neither
acquisition was reportable under the
include the factual and legal basis for the request,
and must identify the specific portions of the
comment to be withheld from the public record. See
FTC Rule 4.9(c), 16 CFR 4.9(c).
VerDate Mar<15>2010
18:05 Apr 23, 2013
Jkt 229001
Hart-Scott-Rodino Act. The Consent
Order seeks to restore competition lost
through the acquisitions by requiring
Graco to license certain technology to a
small competitor to facilitate its entry
and expansion, and to cease and desist
from engaging in certain conduct that
may delay or prevent entry and
expansion of competing firms. The
Complaint and Consent Order in this
matter have been issued as final and the
Consent Order is now effective.
The Complaint alleges that the
acquisitions each violated Section 7 of
the Clayton Act, as amended, 15 U.S.C.
18, and Section 5 of the Federal Trade
Commission Act, as amended, 15 U.S.C.
45.
The purpose of this Analysis to Aid
Public Comment is to invite and
facilitate public comment concerning
the Consent Order. It is not intended to
constitute an official interpretation of
the Agreement and Consent Order or in
any way to modify their terms.
The Consent Order is for settlement
purposes only. The Commission has
placed the Consent Order on the public
record for thirty (30) days for the receipt
of comments by interested persons.
I. The Relevant Market and Market
Structure
The relevant market within which to
analyze the competitive effects of these
acquisitions is fast-set equipment used
by contractors in North America. Fastset equipment combines and applies
various reactive chemicals that form
polyurethane foams or polyurea
coatings used for the application of
insulation and protective coatings. The
essential components of a fast-set
equipment system are the proportioner,
the heated hoses, and the spray gun.
Fast-set equipment manufacturers sell
their products almost exclusively
through a network of specialized, thirdparty distributors. These independent
distributors sell to end-users. End-users
demand a proximate source of expertise,
spare parts, and repair services.
Therefore, a robust network of thirdparty fast-set equipment distributors is
necessary for any manufacturer to
compete effectively in the relevant
market.
Prior to its acquisition by Respondent
in 2005, Gusmer was the largest and
most significant competitor engaged in
the manufacture and sale of a full line
of fast-set equipment throughout North
America and the world. The acquisition
increased Graco’s share of the North
American fast-set equipment market to
over 65%, and left GlasCraft as Graco’s
only significant North American
competitor. Graco’s acquisition of
GlasCraft in 2008 raised Graco’s market
PO 00000
Frm 00053
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
share above 90% and removed Graco’s
last significant North American
competitor. Following the acquisitions
of each of Gusmer and GlasCraft, Graco
closed both firms’ fast-set equipment
manufacturing facilities and has fully
assimilated or terminated all remaining
assets, products, intellectual property,
and personnel from both firms.
Prior to the acquisitions, fast-set
equipment distributors typically carried
products from multiple manufacturers.
Distributors and end-users were able to
mix and match the products from the
different manufacturers to assemble a
fast-set system that best satisfied endusers’ demands. Further, manufacturers
did not impose exclusive relationships
on distributors—a distributor was free to
make some or all of its fast-set
equipment purchases from whichever
manufacturers it chose. The Complaint
alleges, among other effects, that the
acquisitions of Gusmer and GlasCraft
have removed the ability of distributors
and end-users to select the equipment
that best serves their, and their
customers’, interests and needs.
II. Conditions of Entry and Expansion
The Complaint alleges high entry
barriers in the relevant market. The
principal barrier to entry is the need for
specialized third-party distribution. As
a result of its acquisitions, Graco
obtained substantial control over access
to that distribution channel. Subsequent
Graco practices have further heightened
barriers to competitive entry and
expansion, such that restoration of the
competition lost as a result of Graco’s
acquisitions is unlikely to be restored
unless Graco’s continuation of those
practices is enjoined.
Beginning in 2007, former employees
of Gusmer began distributing fast-set
equipment as Gama Machinery USA,
Inc., now doing business as
Polyurethane Machinery Corp. (‘‘Gama/
PMC’’). In March 2008, Graco sued
Gama/PMC and others alleging, among
other things, breach of contract. The
continuation of that litigation has
reduced the willingness of distributors
to purchase fast-set equipment from
Gama/PMC, for fear that their supply of
fast-set equipment might later be
interrupted as a result of litigation. To
reduce that barrier, an impending
settlement of that litigation is
incorporated in the Commission’s
Consent Order.
Like Gama/PMC, other prospective
competitors—some of which presently
offer only some components, rather than
a full line of proportioners, hoses, and
spray guns—have been unable to gain a
meaningful foothold in the North
American fast-set equipment market
E:\FR\FM\24APN1.SGM
24APN1
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 79 / Wednesday, April 24, 2013 / Notices
because of barriers to access to the
required specialty distribution channel.
Following its obtaining of market power
through its acquisitions, Graco
increased the discount and inventory
thresholds it required of distributors,
and threatened to cut off any
distributor’s access to needed Graco
fast-set equipment if the distributor
purchased fast-set equipment from any
Graco rival. The reduction of barriers to
entry and expansion by enjoining the
continuation of this conduct is
necessary to the restoration of
competition lost as a result of Graco’s
acquisitions, and certain provisions of
the Commission’s cease and desist order
are directed to that end.
tkelley on DSK3SPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
III. Effects of Graco’s Acquisitions
As a result of the acquisitions, Graco
has eliminated head-to-head
competition with Gusmer and GlasCraft.
The Complaint alleges that
concentration in the relevant market has
increased substantially, and given Graco
the ability to exercise market power
unilaterally. The Complaint alleges that
Graco has exercised that market power
by raising prices, reducing product
options and alternatives, and reducing
innovation. The Complaint further
alleges that Graco engaged in certain
post-acquisition conduct that has raised
barriers to entry and expansion such
that the continuation of that conduct
must be enjoined if the competition lost
as a result of Graco’s acquisitions is to
be restored.
IV. The Consent Agreement
Since the acquisitions were
completed some time ago, it is not
practicable to recreate the acquired
firms as independent going concerns.
Instead, the purpose of the Consent
Order is to ensure the restoration of the
competitive conditions that existed
before the acquisitions, to the extent
possible, by facilitating Gama/PMC’s
entry and expansion and lowering
barriers to entry. Therefore, the Consent
Order requires Graco to enter into a
settlement agreement with Gama/PMC
within ten (10) days of the entry of the
Order. In addition, Graco must grant to
Gama/PMC an irrevocable license to
certain Graco patents and other
intellectual property in order to ensure
that Graco cannot continue or renew its
suit. In exchange, PMC will pay to
Graco a sum of money for the settlement
of the litigation and agree to a deferred
license fee for the intellectual property.
The settlement documents will be
incorporated by reference into the
Consent Order, and cannot be modified
without the Commission’s prior
approval. Further, the Consent Order
VerDate Mar<15>2010
18:05 Apr 23, 2013
Jkt 229001
independently prohibits Graco from
filing suit against Gama/PMC for
infringing the licensed intellectual
property.
In order to reduce barriers to
competitor entry, the Consent Order
directs Graco to cease and desist from
imposing any conditions on its
distributors that could, directly or
indirectly, lead to exclusivity. The
Consent Order also prohibits Graco from
discriminating against, coercing,
threatening, or in any other manner
pressuring its distributors not to carry or
service any competing fast-set
equipment. The Consent Order does not
mandate that any distributor carry
competitive fast-set equipment; rather, it
bars Graco from imposing exclusivity on
its distributors.
The Consent Order further obligates
Graco to waive or modify any policies
or contracts that would violate the
Consent Order. Graco will have thirty
(30) days after the Consent Order is final
to negotiate changes in the contracts
with its distributors to comply with the
Consent Order. Graco must provide all
of its distributors, employees and agents
with a copy of the Consent Order and
a plain-language explanation of what is
says and requires.
The Consent Order further requires
Graco to provide the Commission with
prior notice: (1) If it intends to make
another acquisition of fast-set
equipment (after an appropriate waiting
period); or (2) if it intends, within thirty
(30) days, to institute a lawsuit or
similar legal action against a distributor
or end-user with regard to a claimed
violation of Graco’s trade secrets or
other intellectual property covering fastset equipment. The Consent Order will
remain in effect for ten (10) years, and
contains standard compliance and
reporting requirements.
V. Effective Date of the Consent Order
and Opportunity for Public Comment
In this instance, the Commission
issued the Complaint and the Consent
Order as final, and served them upon
Graco at the same time it accepted the
Consent Agreement for public comment.
As a result of this action, the Consent
Order has become effective. The
Commission adopted procedures in
August 1999 to allow for immediate
implementation of an order prior to the
public comment period. The
Commission announced that it
‘‘contemplates doing so only in
exceptional cases where, for example, it
believes that the allegedly unlawful
conduct to be prohibited threatens
substantial and imminent public harm.’’
64 FR 46,267, 46,268 (1999).
PO 00000
Frm 00054
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
24203
This is an appropriate case in which
to issue a final order before receiving
public comment because the
effectiveness of the remedy depends on
the timeliness of the private settlement
agreement between Graco and Gama/
PMC, which only becomes effective
when the Consent Order becomes final.
Both Graco and Gama/PMC have made
initial efforts to address distributor
concerns about possible Graco
retribution by separately sending letters
to distributors assuring them that
preliminary discussions of business
relations with Gama/PMC would not
have any adverse consequences on the
distributors’ relationship with Graco.
However, the protections of the
applicable license and covenants, as
well as those included in the Consent
Order, are needed to provide
distributors reasonable assurances that
buying from Gama/PMC will not
jeopardize the distributors’ relationship
with Graco. As a result, any delay in the
effectiveness of the Consent Order and
the associated private settlement will
prevent Gama/PMC from finalizing
relationships with distributors in time
for the current construction season—
and this will have a significant and
meaningful impact on competition in
the fast-set equipment market that the
Consent Order is intended to foster.
The Commission anticipates that the
competitive problems alleged in the
Complaint will be remedied by the
Consent Order, as issued. Nonetheless,
public comments are encouraged and
will be considered by the Commission.
The purpose of this analysis is to invite
and facilitate such comments
concerning the Consent Order and to aid
the Commission in determining whether
to modify the Consent Order in any
respect. Therefore, the Complaint and
Consent Order have been placed on the
public record for thirty (30) days to
solicit comments from interested
persons. Comments received during this
period will become part of the public
record. After thirty (30) days, the
Commission will again review the
comments received, and may determine
that the Consent Order should be
modified in response to the comments.2
2 If the Respondent does not agree to any such
modifications, the Commission may (1) initiate a
proceeding to reopen and modify the Consent Order
in accordance with Rule 3.72(b), 16 CFR 3.72(b), or
(2) commence a new administrative proceeding by
issuing an administrative complaint in accordance
with Rule 3.11. See 16 CFR 2.34(e)(2).
E:\FR\FM\24APN1.SGM
24APN1
24204
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 79 / Wednesday, April 24, 2013 / Notices
tkelley on DSK3SPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
By direction of the Commission.
Donald S. Clark,
Secretary.
Statement of the Federal Trade
Commission
Today the Commission has voted
unanimously to approve the Complaint
and Decision & Order (‘‘Order’’) against
Graco, Inc. (‘‘Graco’’) to resolve
allegations that it violated Section 7 of
the Clayton Act when it acquired
Gusmer Corp. (‘‘Gusmer’’) in 2005 and
Glascraft, Inc. (‘‘Glascraft’’) in 2008. At
the time of the acquisitions, Gusmer and
Glascraft were Graco’s two closest
competitors in the market for fast-set
equipment (‘‘FSE’’) used to apply
polyurethane and polyurea coatings.
The acquisitions eliminated the only
significant competition in the market,
and resulted in Graco holding a
monopoly position as the only full-line
FSE manufacturer. The Order contains
provisions, including prohibitions on
discriminating against distributors
selling competitors’ FSE products, that
are intended to constrain Graco’s ability
to exclude prospective entrants into the
FSE market by establishing and/or
maintaining exclusive relationships
with its third-party distributors.
Commissioner Wright voted in favor of
the Complaint and Order, but also
issued a statement outlining his
disagreement with these portions of the
Order. We respectfully disagree with
Commissioner Wright, and believe that
these specific provisions are necessary
to remediate the anticompetitive impact
of the two mergers in this case.
The typical remedy for the
Commission in a Section 7 matter is a
divestiture of the illegally acquired
assets (and any other assets necessary to
make the divestiture buyer a viable
competitor). Pursuing such a remedy in
this matter, however, would be difficult,
if not impossible, because Graco had
long ago integrated or discontinued the
product lines it acquired from Gusmer
and Glascraft. There was no easily
severable package of assets that could be
divested to recreate one—much less
two—viable competitors to replace
Gusmer and Glascraft. As a result, the
most effective relief available was a
behavioral remedy intended to facilitate
entry into the FSE market, which, of
course, includes addressing the postacquisition conduct described in the
Complaint that had precluded entry into
the relevant market. Specifically, after
the acquisitions Graco solidified its
market share by locking up third-party
distributors through a series of purchase
and inventory threshold requirements,
as well as threats of retaliation and
termination if distributors carried the
VerDate Mar<15>2010
18:05 Apr 23, 2013
Jkt 229001
products of any remaining or newly
entering FSE manufacturers.
The evidence gathered in the course
of the Commission’s investigation
demonstrates that Graco’s efforts were
successful; no other firm gained more
than five percent of the North American
FSE market and Graco’s market share of
between 90 and 95 percent has
remained intact since its 2008
acquisition of Glascraft. Further, the
investigation uncovered no evidence
that Graco’s post-acquisition conduct
provided any cognizable efficiency that
would benefit consumers. A remedy
that does not address Graco’s ability to
raise and maintain nearly
insurmountable entry barriers is
substantially less likely to return
competition to the FSE market. The
Order provisions that Commissioner
Wright criticizes, in our view, are
integral to achieving that goal but will
not cause market inefficiencies.
We believe that exclusive dealing
relationships can have procompetitive
benefits and that such relationships
should not be condemned in the
absence of a thorough factual and
economic assessment of the
circumstances surrounding such
conduct. But it is equally important to
recognize that, when employed by a
competitor that has acquired significant
market power or monopoly power,
exclusive dealing arrangements have the
potential to cement such power and
prevent or deter entry that would lead
to lower prices, higher quality, and
better service for consumers.3 In any
event, regardless of how one views
exclusive dealing arrangements
generally, there is ample support for the
fencing-in relief prescribed in this
merger settlement, which is designed to
restore competition in the FSE market
lost as a result of Graco’s illegal
acquisitions.
We join Commissioner Wright in
commending the Commission staff for
their hard work in this matter. They
have done an excellent job in
investigating the market involved and
the issues raised during the course of
this investigation.
By direction of the Commission,
Commissioner Wright abstaining.
Donald S. Clark,
Secretary.
3 See, e.g., United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253
F.3d 34, 71–72, 74 (D.C. Cir. 2001) (holding that
Microsoft’s exclusive dealing arrangements with
Internet access providers, independent software
vendors, and Apple violated Sherman Act § 2).
PO 00000
Frm 00055
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
Statement of Commissioner Joshua D.
Wright
The Commission has voted to issue a
Complaint and Order against Graco, Inc.
(‘‘Graco’’) to remedy the allegedly
anticompetitive effects of Graco’s
acquisition of Gusmer Corp. (‘‘Gusmer’’)
in 2005 and GlasCraft, Inc. (‘‘GlasCraft’’)
in 2008. I supported the Commission’s
decision because there is reason to
believe Graco’s acquisitions
substantially lessened competition in
the market for fast-set equipment in
violation of Section 7 of the Clayton
Act. I want to commend staff for their
hard work in this matter. Staff has
conducted a thorough investigation and
developed strong evidence that Graco’s
acquisition of Gusmer and GlasCraft
likely resulted in higher prices and
fewer choices for consumers.
I write separately to discuss two
aspects of the Order with which I
respectfully disagree, namely the
provisions prohibiting Graco from
entering into exclusive dealing contracts
with distributors and establishing
purchase and inventory thresholds that
must be satisfied in order for
distributors to obtain discounts. Both
provisions are aimed at prohibiting
exclusivity or, in the case of purchase
and inventory thresholds, loyalty
discounts that might be viewed as de
facto exclusive arrangements. I am not
persuaded in this case that prohibiting
exclusive dealing contracts and
regulating loyalty discounts will make
consumers better off. To the contrary,
these provisions may lead to reduced
output or higher prices for consumers.
I therefore do not believe the limitations
on such arrangements imposed by the
Order are in the public interest.
I. Appropriate Use of Behavioral
Remedies
The majority and I agree that although
the most suitable remedy for an
anticompetitive merger usually is a
divestiture of assets, under certain
circumstances behavioral remedies may
be appropriate.4 One scenario in which
behavioral remedies may be appropriate
is when the challenged merger has long
since been consummated and
divestiture or other structural remedies
are not a viable option for restoring
competition to pre-merger levels. Given
that Graco has fully integrated Gusmer
and Glascraft and discontinued their
4 See e.g., Fed. Trade Comm’n, Statement of
Federal Trade Commission’s Bureau of Competition
on Negotiating Merger Remedies, at 5 (2012),
available at https://www.ftc.gov/bc/bestpractices/
merger-remediesstmt.pdf (stating the Commission
favors structural relief, such as divestitures, in
horizontal mergers, but that behavioral relief may
be appropriate in some cases).
E:\FR\FM\24APN1.SGM
24APN1
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 79 / Wednesday, April 24, 2013 / Notices
tkelley on DSK3SPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
product lines, divestiture is not an
option and the Commission should
rightly consider whether behavioral
remedies in this case would protect
consumers.
As with merger remedies generally,
when deciding whether and what
behavioral remedy to impose, the
Commission must ultimately be guided
by its mission of protecting consumers.5
Because behavioral remedies displace
normal competitive decision-making in
a market, they pose a particularly high
risk of inadvertently reducing consumer
welfare and should be examined closely
prior to adoption to ensure consumers’
interests are best served. In particular,
effective behavioral remedies must be
‘‘tailored as precisely as possible to the
competitive harms associated with the
merger to avoid unnecessary
entanglements with the competitive
process.’’ 6 Merely showing high market
shares and the unavailability of
structural remedies does not justify
restricting conduct that typically is
procompetitive because these
conditions do not make the conduct any
more likely, much less generally likely,
to be anticompetitive.7 A minimum
safeguard to ensure remedial
provisions—whether described as
fencing-in relief or otherwise—restore
competition rather than inadvertently
reduce it is to require evidence that the
type of conduct being restricted has
been, or is likely to be, used
anticompetitively to harm consumers.
With this analytical framework in
mind, I support those remedies in the
Order that seek to restore pre-merger
competition by imposing restrictions
closely linked to the evidence of
5 The Commission should keep in mind that ours
is not a binary choice simply between imposing a
structural or a behavioral remedy. The most
attractive option from a consumer welfare point of
view for any given circumstance may be to block
the merger in its entirety, allow the merger to
proceed without any remedy, or a hybrid solution
combining some aspects of each of these options.
Having ruled out structural remedies in this case,
the question is which, if any, of the non-structural
alternatives best improves consumer welfare. See
Ken Heyer, Optimal Remedies for Anticompetitive
Mergers, 26 ANTITRUST 27 (2012) (arguing
behavioral remedies are not justified simply
because structural remedies are unavailable, and
that an agency should weigh the economic costs
and benefits of each non-structural alternative,
including doing nothing).
6 U.S. Dep’t of Justice Antitrust Div., Antitrust
Division Policy Guide to Merger Remedies, at 7 n.12
(June 2011), available at https://www.justice.gov/atr/
public/guidelines/272350.pdf; see also, Heyer,
supra note 2, at 27–28 (‘‘[A]mong the most
important considerations in devising a behavioral
remedy is that there be a close nexus between the
remedy imposed and the theory of harm motivating
its use.’’).
7 In fact, efficiencies justifications for exclusive
dealing contracts apply, and some even more
strongly, when a firm has market power.
VerDate Mar<15>2010
19:28 Apr 23, 2013
Jkt 229001
anticompetitive harm in this case. For
instance, staff uncovered evidence
Graco threatened distributors that
considered carrying fast-set equipment
sold by competing manufacturers, and
that these threats actually led to
distributors not purchasing the
competing products. Staff also learned
that distributors refused to purchase
fast-set equipment from Gama/PMC, one
of the few fringe competitors remaining
after Graco’s acquisitions, because of the
uncertainty resulting from Graco’s
lawsuit against Gama/PMC. The Order
thus appropriately prohibits Graco from
retaliating against distributors that
consider purchasing fast-set equipment
from other manufacturers 8 and requires
Graco to settle its lawsuit against Gama/
PMC.
In contrast, and as is discussed in
more detail below, there is insufficient
evidence linking the remedial
provisions in the Order prohibiting
exclusive dealing contracts and
regulating loyalty discounts to the
anticompetitive harm in this case.
II. Prohibitions on Exclusive Dealing
It is widely accepted that exclusive
dealing and de facto exclusive
contracts—while generally efficiency
enhancing—can lead to anticompetitive
results when certain conditions are
satisfied. The primary competitive
concern is that exclusive dealing may be
used by a monopolist to raise rivals’
costs of distribution by depriving them
the opportunity to compete for
distribution sufficient to achieve
efficient scale, and ultimately harm
consumers by putting competitors out of
business.9 On the other hand, the
economic literature is replete with
procompetitive justifications for
exclusive dealing, including aligning
the incentives of manufacturers and
distributors, preventing free-riding, and
facilitating relationship-specific
8 Such retaliatory conduct alone is outside the
normal competitive process and has no plausible
procompetitive benefit. Its proscription therefore is
unlikely to harm consumers. Of course, a decision
by Graco to refuse to sell to distributors who do not
enter into an exclusive contract should not itself be
proscribed as illegitimate retaliation.
9 See e.g., Alden F. Abbott & Joshua D. Wright,
Antitrust Analysis of Tying Arrangements and
Exclusive Dealing, in ANTITRUST LAW AND ECONOMICS
183, 194–96 (Keith N. Hylton ed., 2d ed. 2010).
There also are novel theories of anticompetitive
harm, including models exploring the possibility
that certain types of discount programs effectively
impose a tax upon distributors’ choice to expand
rivals’ sales and thereby potentially prevent rivals
from acquiring a sufficient number of retailers to
cover the fixed costs of entry. See e.g., Joe Farrell,
et al., Economics at the FTC: Mergers, DominantFirm Conduct, and Consumer Behavior, 37 (4) REV.
INDUS. ORG. 263 (2010).
PO 00000
Frm 00056
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
24205
investments.10 In fact, the empirical
evidence substantially supports the
view that exclusive dealing
arrangements are much more likely to
be procompetitive than
anticompetitive.11
Because exclusive dealing contracts
typically are procompetitive and a part
of the normal competitive process, the
Commission should only restrict the use
of such arrangements when there is
sufficient evidence that they have or are
likely to decrease consumer welfare.
This ensures consumers the merger
remedy does not deprive them the fruits
of the competitive process. The
evidence in this case is insufficient to
conclude that Graco has used, or
intends to use, exclusive dealing or de
facto exclusive contracts to foreclose
rivals and ultimately harm consumers.
To the contrary, the Commission’s
Complaint describes the fast-set
equipment market as one particularly
well suited for exclusive arrangements.
Specifically, the Complaint
acknowledges the sale of fast-set
equipment demands specialized third
party distributors that possess the
technical expertise to teach consumers
how to use and maintain the
manufacturer’s equipment.12 One could
therefore easily imagine that
manufacturers might only be willing to
provide training to distributors if they
have some assurance that current or
future competitors will be unable to free
ride on their investments in the
distributors’ technical expertise.
Exclusive dealing arrangements with
distributors are one well-known and
common method of preventing such free
riding.
The provisions in the Order
prohibiting exclusive contracts therefore
may needlessly harm consumers by
deterring potentially procompetitive
arrangements. For that reason, I do not
believe that provision is in the public
interest.
III. Restrictions on Loyalty Discounts
The primary anticompetitive concerns
with loyalty discounts are analytically
similar to those associated with
exclusive dealing and de facto exclusive
10 See e.g., Abbott & Wright, supra note 6, at 200–
01; Francine Lafontaine & Margaret Slade, Exclusive
Contracts and Vertical Restraints: Empirical
Evidence and Public Policy, in HANDBOOK OF
ANTITRUST ECONOMICS, 393–94 (Paolo Buccirossi,
ed., 2008); Benjamin Klein & Kevin Murphy,
Exclusive Dealing Intensifies Competition for
Distribution, 75 ANTITRUST L. J. 433, 465 (2008).
11 See e.g., Abbott & Wright, supra note 6, at 200–
01; Lafontaine & Slade, supra note 7, at 393–94.
12 Complaint ¶ 24, Graco, Inc., FTC File No.101–
0215, (April 17, 2013).
E:\FR\FM\24APN1.SGM
24APN1
24206
Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 79 / Wednesday, April 24, 2013 / Notices
tkelley on DSK3SPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
contracts.13 As with exclusive dealing,
the economic literature also supports
the view that loyalty discounts more
often than not are procompetitive.14 The
Commission’s competition mission
therefore is best served by an approach
that counsels against imposing
restrictions on loyalty discounts unless
there is sufficient evidence to establish
that such arrangements have or are
likely to harm competition and
consumers.
The Order permits Graco to enter into
certain loyalty discount agreements that
require distributors to meet annual
purchase and inventory thresholds to
qualify for discounted prices.15 The
Order, however, restricts the scope of
these loyalty discounts by prescribing
the maximum threshold levels Graco
may set in 2013 and by only allowing
those maximums to increase by 5
percent year to year. Although there is
evidence that Graco in some instances
increased the inventory and purchase
thresholds it required distributors to
meet to receive discounts on fast-set
equipment following its acquisitions, I
have not seen evidence sufficient to link
these increases to the anticompetitive
effects of the mergers alleged in the
Commission’s Complaint. For example,
I have seen no evidence that a
distributor dropped Gama/PMC or any
other fringe competitor in response to
Graco’s increased thresholds. Further,
although there appears to be evidence
that at least some distributors are unable
to both meet the thresholds necessary to
receive Graco’s discounts and carry
competing manufacturers’ products,
there is nothing barring these
distributors from forgoing those
discounts in order to carry multiple
products lines. It has been several years
since Graco increased the thresholds. In
the absence of evidence this change
harmed competition, the fact that some
distributors prefer to take the discounts
is not a sufficient reason to believe that
prohibiting these contracts will protect
consumers. Moreover, it is unlikely that
the Commission is best positioned to
gauge what the appropriate threshold
should be for each distributor over time
and as market conditions change.
As a result, based upon the available
evidence, I am concerned the
restrictions on loyalty discounts in the
13 See generally Bruce H. Kobayashi, The
Economics of Loyalty Discount and Antitrust Law
in the United States, 1 COMP. POL’Y INT’L 115 (2005).
14 Id.
15 Decision & Order § III(6)(c), Graco, Inc., FTC
File No.101–0215, (April 17, 2013).
VerDate Mar<15>2010
19:28 Apr 23, 2013
Jkt 229001
Order ultimately may reduce consumer
welfare rather than protect competition.
Thus, I do not believe this aspect of the
Order is in the public interest.
*
*
*
*
*
For these reasons, I voted in favor of
the Commission’s Complaint and Order,
but respectfully disagree with the Order
provisions prohibiting exclusive
contracts and restricting loyalty
discounts. To the extent the majority
believes Graco may use such
arrangements to engage in
anticompetitive conduct in the future,
the Commission’s willingness and
ability to bring a monopolization claim
where the evidence indicates it is
appropriate would protect consumers
against the competitive risks posed by
these arrangements without depriving
consumers of their potential benefits.
[FR Doc. 2013–09673 Filed 4–23–13; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6750–01–P
GENERAL SERVICES
ADMINISTRATION
[OMB Control No. 3090–00xx; Docket 2013–
0001; Sequence 5]
Agency Information Collection
Activities; Information Collection; USA
Spending
Interagency Policy and
Management Division, Office of
Governmentwide Policy, U.S. General
Services Administration (GSA).
ACTION: Notice of request for public
comments regarding a new OMB
clearance.
AGENCY:
Under the provisions of the
Paperwork Reduction Act, the General
Services Administration will be
submitting to the Office of Management
and Budget (OMB) a request to review
and approve a new information
collection requirement regarding USA
Spending.
SUMMARY:
Submit comments on or before
June 24, 2013.
ADDRESSES: Submit comments
identified by Information Collection
3090–00xx, USA Spending, by any of
the following methods:
• Regulations.gov: https://
www.regulations.gov. Submit comments
via the Federal eRulemaking portal by
searching the OMB control number.
Select the link ‘‘Submit a Comment’’
that corresponds with ‘‘Information
Collection 3090–00xx, USA Spending.’’
Follow the instructions provided at the
DATES:
PO 00000
Frm 00057
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
‘‘Submit a Comment’’ screen. Please
include your name, company name (if
any), and ‘‘Information Collection 3090–
00xx, USA Spending’’ on your attached
document.
• Fax: 202–501–4067.
• Mail: General Services
Administration, Regulatory Secretariat
(MVCB), 1275 First Street NE.,
Washington, DC 20417. ATTN: Hada
Flowers/IC 3090–00xx, USA Spending.
Instructions: Please submit comments
only and cite Information Collection
3090–00xx, USA Spending, in all
correspondence related to this
collection. All comments received will
be posted without change to https://
www.regulations.gov, including any
personal and/or business confidential
information provided.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
Mary Searcy, Acquisition Systems for
Award Management Division, Office of
Governmentwide Policy, General
Services Administration, 1275 First
Street NE., Washington, DC 20417;
telephone number: 703–603–8132; or
email address Mary.Searcy@gsa.gov.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION:
A. Purpose
USASpending.gov is required by the
Federal Funding Accountability and
Transparency Act (Transparency Act).
The site provides the public with
information about how tax dollars are
spent. The site provides data about the
various types of contracts, grants, loans
and other types of spending in the
federal government.
B. Annual Reporting Burden
Number of Respondents: 5,000.
Responses per Respondent: 1.
Total Responses: 5,000.
Average Burden Hours per Response:
.25.
Total Burden Hours: 1250.
Obtaining Copies of Proposals:
Requesters may obtain a copy of the
information collection documents from
the General Services Administration,
Regulatory Secretariat (MVCB), 1275
First Street NE., Washington, DC 20417,
telephone (202) 501–4755. Please cite
OMB Control Number 3090–00xx, USA
Spending, in all correspondence.
Dated: April 17, 2013.
Casey Coleman,
Chief Information Officer.
[FR Doc. 2013–09573 Filed 4–23–13; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6820–WY–P
E:\FR\FM\24APN1.SGM
24APN1
Agencies
[Federal Register Volume 78, Number 79 (Wednesday, April 24, 2013)]
[Notices]
[Pages 24201-24206]
From the Federal Register Online via the Government Printing Office [www.gpo.gov]
[FR Doc No: 2013-09673]
=======================================================================
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION
[File No. 101 0215]
Graco, Inc.; Analysis of Agreement Containing Consent Order To
Aid Public Comment
AGENCY: Federal Trade Commission.
ACTION: Proposed Consent Agreement.
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
SUMMARY: The consent agreement in this matter settles alleged
violations of federal law prohibiting unfair or deceptive acts or
practices or unfair methods of competition. The attached Analysis to
Aid Public Comment describes both the allegations in the draft
complaint and the terms of the consent order--embodied in the consent
agreement--that would settle these allegations.
DATES: Comments must be received on or before May 20, 2013.
ADDRESSES: Interested parties may file a comment at https://ftcpublic.commentworks.com/ftc/gracoconsent online or on paper, by
following the instructions in the Request for Comment part of the
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION section below. Write ``Graco, File No. 101
0215'' on your comment and file your comment online at https://ftcpublic.commentworks.com/ftc/gracoconsent by following the
instructions on the web-based form. If you prefer to file your comment
on paper, mail or deliver your comment to the following address:
Federal Trade Commission, Office of the Secretary, Room H-113 (Annex
D), 600 Pennsylvania Avenue NW., Washington, DC 20580.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: Benjamin Jackson (202-326-2193), FTC,
Bureau of Competition, 600 Pennsylvania Avenue NW., Washington, DC
20580.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: Pursuant to Section 6(f) of the Federal
Trade Commission Act, 15 U.S.C. 46(f), and FTC Rule 2.34, 16 CFR 2.34,
notice is hereby given that the above-captioned consent agreement
containing a consent order to cease and desist, having been filed with
and accepted, subject to final approval, by the Commission, has been
placed on the public record for a period of thirty (30) days. The
following Analysis to Aid Public Comment describes the terms of the
consent agreement, and the allegations in the complaint. An electronic
copy of the full text of the consent agreement package can be obtained
from the FTC Home Page (for April 18, 2013), on the World Wide Web, at
https://www.ftc.gov/os/actions.shtm. A paper copy can be obtained from
the FTC Public Reference Room, Room 130-H, 600 Pennsylvania Avenue NW.,
Washington, DC 20580, either in person or by calling (202) 326-2222.
You can file a comment online or on paper. For the Commission to
consider your comment, we must receive it on or before May 20, 2013.
Write ``Graco, File No. 101 0215'' on your comment. Your comment--
including your name and your state--will be placed on the public record
of this proceeding, including, to the extent practicable, on the public
Commission Web site, at https://www.ftc.gov/os/publiccomments.shtm. As a
matter of discretion, the Commission tries to remove individuals' home
contact information from comments before placing them on the Commission
Web site.
Because your comment will be made public, you are solely
responsible for making sure that your comment does not include any
sensitive personal information, like anyone's Social Security number,
date of birth, driver's license number or other state identification
number or foreign country equivalent, passport number, financial
account number, or credit or debit card number. You are also solely
responsible for making sure that your comment does not include any
sensitive health information, like medical records or other
individually identifiable health information. In addition, do not
include any ``[t]rade secret or any commercial or financial information
which * * * is privileged or confidential,'' as discussed in Section
6(f) of the FTC Act, 15 U.S.C. 46(f), and FTC Rule 4.10(a)(2), 16 CFR
4.10(a)(2). In particular, do not include competitively sensitive
information such as costs, sales statistics, inventories, formulas,
patterns, devices, manufacturing processes, or customer names.
If you want the Commission to give your comment confidential
treatment, you must file it in paper form, with a request for
confidential treatment, and you have to follow the procedure explained
in FTC Rule 4.9(c), 16 CFR 4.9(c).\1\ Your comment will be kept
[[Page 24202]]
confidential only if the FTC General Counsel, in his or her sole
discretion, grants your request in accordance with the law and the
public interest.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1\ In particular, the written request for confidential
treatment that accompanies the comment must include the factual and
legal basis for the request, and must identify the specific portions
of the comment to be withheld from the public record. See FTC Rule
4.9(c), 16 CFR 4.9(c).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Postal mail addressed to the Commission is subject to delay due to
heightened security screening. As a result, we encourage you to submit
your comments online. To make sure that the Commission considers your
online comment, you must file it at https://ftcpublic.commentworks.com/ftc/gracoconsent by following the instructions on the web-based form.
If this Notice appears at https://www.regulations.gov/#!home, you also
may file a comment through that Web site.
If you file your comment on paper, write ``Graco, File No. 101
0215'' on your comment and on the envelope, and mail or deliver it to
the following address: Federal Trade Commission, Office of the
Secretary, Room H-113 (Annex D), 600 Pennsylvania Avenue NW.,
Washington, DC 20580. If possible, submit your paper comment to the
Commission by courier or overnight service.
Visit the Commission Web site at https://www.ftc.gov to read this
Notice and the news release describing it. The FTC Act and other laws
that the Commission administers permit the collection of public
comments to consider and use in this proceeding as appropriate. The
Commission will consider all timely and responsive public comments that
it receives on or before May 20, 2013. You can find more information,
including routine uses permitted by the Privacy Act, in the
Commission's privacy policy, at https://www.ftc.gov/ftc/privacy.htm.
Analysis of Agreement Containing Consent Order To Aid Public Comment
The Federal Trade Commission (``Commission'') has accepted for
public comment an Agreement Containing Consent Order (``Consent
Order'') with Graco, Inc. (``Graco'') to remedy the alleged
anticompetitive effects resulting from Graco's acquisition of its most
significant competitors, Gusmer Corp. (``Gusmer'') and GlasCraft, Inc.
(``GlasCraft''). The Commission Complaint (``Complaint'') alleges that,
at the time of the acquisitions, Graco, Gusmer, and GlasCraft each
manufactured and sold equipment for the application of fast-set
chemicals (``fast-set equipment''). Neither acquisition was reportable
under the Hart-Scott-Rodino Act. The Consent Order seeks to restore
competition lost through the acquisitions by requiring Graco to license
certain technology to a small competitor to facilitate its entry and
expansion, and to cease and desist from engaging in certain conduct
that may delay or prevent entry and expansion of competing firms. The
Complaint and Consent Order in this matter have been issued as final
and the Consent Order is now effective.
The Complaint alleges that the acquisitions each violated Section 7
of the Clayton Act, as amended, 15 U.S.C. 18, and Section 5 of the
Federal Trade Commission Act, as amended, 15 U.S.C. 45.
The purpose of this Analysis to Aid Public Comment is to invite and
facilitate public comment concerning the Consent Order. It is not
intended to constitute an official interpretation of the Agreement and
Consent Order or in any way to modify their terms.
The Consent Order is for settlement purposes only. The Commission
has placed the Consent Order on the public record for thirty (30) days
for the receipt of comments by interested persons.
I. The Relevant Market and Market Structure
The relevant market within which to analyze the competitive effects
of these acquisitions is fast-set equipment used by contractors in
North America. Fast-set equipment combines and applies various reactive
chemicals that form polyurethane foams or polyurea coatings used for
the application of insulation and protective coatings. The essential
components of a fast-set equipment system are the proportioner, the
heated hoses, and the spray gun.
Fast-set equipment manufacturers sell their products almost
exclusively through a network of specialized, third-party distributors.
These independent distributors sell to end-users. End-users demand a
proximate source of expertise, spare parts, and repair services.
Therefore, a robust network of third-party fast-set equipment
distributors is necessary for any manufacturer to compete effectively
in the relevant market.
Prior to its acquisition by Respondent in 2005, Gusmer was the
largest and most significant competitor engaged in the manufacture and
sale of a full line of fast-set equipment throughout North America and
the world. The acquisition increased Graco's share of the North
American fast-set equipment market to over 65%, and left GlasCraft as
Graco's only significant North American competitor. Graco's acquisition
of GlasCraft in 2008 raised Graco's market share above 90% and removed
Graco's last significant North American competitor. Following the
acquisitions of each of Gusmer and GlasCraft, Graco closed both firms'
fast-set equipment manufacturing facilities and has fully assimilated
or terminated all remaining assets, products, intellectual property,
and personnel from both firms.
Prior to the acquisitions, fast-set equipment distributors
typically carried products from multiple manufacturers. Distributors
and end-users were able to mix and match the products from the
different manufacturers to assemble a fast-set system that best
satisfied end-users' demands. Further, manufacturers did not impose
exclusive relationships on distributors--a distributor was free to make
some or all of its fast-set equipment purchases from whichever
manufacturers it chose. The Complaint alleges, among other effects,
that the acquisitions of Gusmer and GlasCraft have removed the ability
of distributors and end-users to select the equipment that best serves
their, and their customers', interests and needs.
II. Conditions of Entry and Expansion
The Complaint alleges high entry barriers in the relevant market.
The principal barrier to entry is the need for specialized third-party
distribution. As a result of its acquisitions, Graco obtained
substantial control over access to that distribution channel.
Subsequent Graco practices have further heightened barriers to
competitive entry and expansion, such that restoration of the
competition lost as a result of Graco's acquisitions is unlikely to be
restored unless Graco's continuation of those practices is enjoined.
Beginning in 2007, former employees of Gusmer began distributing
fast-set equipment as Gama Machinery USA, Inc., now doing business as
Polyurethane Machinery Corp. (``Gama/PMC''). In March 2008, Graco sued
Gama/PMC and others alleging, among other things, breach of contract.
The continuation of that litigation has reduced the willingness of
distributors to purchase fast-set equipment from Gama/PMC, for fear
that their supply of fast-set equipment might later be interrupted as a
result of litigation. To reduce that barrier, an impending settlement
of that litigation is incorporated in the Commission's Consent Order.
Like Gama/PMC, other prospective competitors--some of which
presently offer only some components, rather than a full line of
proportioners, hoses, and spray guns--have been unable to gain a
meaningful foothold in the North American fast-set equipment market
[[Page 24203]]
because of barriers to access to the required specialty distribution
channel. Following its obtaining of market power through its
acquisitions, Graco increased the discount and inventory thresholds it
required of distributors, and threatened to cut off any distributor's
access to needed Graco fast-set equipment if the distributor purchased
fast-set equipment from any Graco rival. The reduction of barriers to
entry and expansion by enjoining the continuation of this conduct is
necessary to the restoration of competition lost as a result of Graco's
acquisitions, and certain provisions of the Commission's cease and
desist order are directed to that end.
III. Effects of Graco's Acquisitions
As a result of the acquisitions, Graco has eliminated head-to-head
competition with Gusmer and GlasCraft. The Complaint alleges that
concentration in the relevant market has increased substantially, and
given Graco the ability to exercise market power unilaterally. The
Complaint alleges that Graco has exercised that market power by raising
prices, reducing product options and alternatives, and reducing
innovation. The Complaint further alleges that Graco engaged in certain
post-acquisition conduct that has raised barriers to entry and
expansion such that the continuation of that conduct must be enjoined
if the competition lost as a result of Graco's acquisitions is to be
restored.
IV. The Consent Agreement
Since the acquisitions were completed some time ago, it is not
practicable to recreate the acquired firms as independent going
concerns. Instead, the purpose of the Consent Order is to ensure the
restoration of the competitive conditions that existed before the
acquisitions, to the extent possible, by facilitating Gama/PMC's entry
and expansion and lowering barriers to entry. Therefore, the Consent
Order requires Graco to enter into a settlement agreement with Gama/PMC
within ten (10) days of the entry of the Order. In addition, Graco must
grant to Gama/PMC an irrevocable license to certain Graco patents and
other intellectual property in order to ensure that Graco cannot
continue or renew its suit. In exchange, PMC will pay to Graco a sum of
money for the settlement of the litigation and agree to a deferred
license fee for the intellectual property. The settlement documents
will be incorporated by reference into the Consent Order, and cannot be
modified without the Commission's prior approval. Further, the Consent
Order independently prohibits Graco from filing suit against Gama/PMC
for infringing the licensed intellectual property.
In order to reduce barriers to competitor entry, the Consent Order
directs Graco to cease and desist from imposing any conditions on its
distributors that could, directly or indirectly, lead to exclusivity.
The Consent Order also prohibits Graco from discriminating against,
coercing, threatening, or in any other manner pressuring its
distributors not to carry or service any competing fast-set equipment.
The Consent Order does not mandate that any distributor carry
competitive fast-set equipment; rather, it bars Graco from imposing
exclusivity on its distributors.
The Consent Order further obligates Graco to waive or modify any
policies or contracts that would violate the Consent Order. Graco will
have thirty (30) days after the Consent Order is final to negotiate
changes in the contracts with its distributors to comply with the
Consent Order. Graco must provide all of its distributors, employees
and agents with a copy of the Consent Order and a plain-language
explanation of what is says and requires.
The Consent Order further requires Graco to provide the Commission
with prior notice: (1) If it intends to make another acquisition of
fast-set equipment (after an appropriate waiting period); or (2) if it
intends, within thirty (30) days, to institute a lawsuit or similar
legal action against a distributor or end-user with regard to a claimed
violation of Graco's trade secrets or other intellectual property
covering fast-set equipment. The Consent Order will remain in effect
for ten (10) years, and contains standard compliance and reporting
requirements.
V. Effective Date of the Consent Order and Opportunity for Public
Comment
In this instance, the Commission issued the Complaint and the
Consent Order as final, and served them upon Graco at the same time it
accepted the Consent Agreement for public comment. As a result of this
action, the Consent Order has become effective. The Commission adopted
procedures in August 1999 to allow for immediate implementation of an
order prior to the public comment period. The Commission announced that
it ``contemplates doing so only in exceptional cases where, for
example, it believes that the allegedly unlawful conduct to be
prohibited threatens substantial and imminent public harm.'' 64 FR
46,267, 46,268 (1999).
This is an appropriate case in which to issue a final order before
receiving public comment because the effectiveness of the remedy
depends on the timeliness of the private settlement agreement between
Graco and Gama/PMC, which only becomes effective when the Consent Order
becomes final. Both Graco and Gama/PMC have made initial efforts to
address distributor concerns about possible Graco retribution by
separately sending letters to distributors assuring them that
preliminary discussions of business relations with Gama/PMC would not
have any adverse consequences on the distributors' relationship with
Graco. However, the protections of the applicable license and
covenants, as well as those included in the Consent Order, are needed
to provide distributors reasonable assurances that buying from Gama/PMC
will not jeopardize the distributors' relationship with Graco. As a
result, any delay in the effectiveness of the Consent Order and the
associated private settlement will prevent Gama/PMC from finalizing
relationships with distributors in time for the current construction
season--and this will have a significant and meaningful impact on
competition in the fast-set equipment market that the Consent Order is
intended to foster.
The Commission anticipates that the competitive problems alleged in
the Complaint will be remedied by the Consent Order, as issued.
Nonetheless, public comments are encouraged and will be considered by
the Commission. The purpose of this analysis is to invite and
facilitate such comments concerning the Consent Order and to aid the
Commission in determining whether to modify the Consent Order in any
respect. Therefore, the Complaint and Consent Order have been placed on
the public record for thirty (30) days to solicit comments from
interested persons. Comments received during this period will become
part of the public record. After thirty (30) days, the Commission will
again review the comments received, and may determine that the Consent
Order should be modified in response to the comments.\2\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\2\ If the Respondent does not agree to any such modifications,
the Commission may (1) initiate a proceeding to reopen and modify
the Consent Order in accordance with Rule 3.72(b), 16 CFR 3.72(b),
or (2) commence a new administrative proceeding by issuing an
administrative complaint in accordance with Rule 3.11. See 16 CFR
2.34(e)(2).
[[Page 24204]]
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
By direction of the Commission.
Donald S. Clark,
Secretary.
Statement of the Federal Trade Commission
Today the Commission has voted unanimously to approve the Complaint
and Decision & Order (``Order'') against Graco, Inc. (``Graco'') to
resolve allegations that it violated Section 7 of the Clayton Act when
it acquired Gusmer Corp. (``Gusmer'') in 2005 and Glascraft, Inc.
(``Glascraft'') in 2008. At the time of the acquisitions, Gusmer and
Glascraft were Graco's two closest competitors in the market for fast-
set equipment (``FSE'') used to apply polyurethane and polyurea
coatings. The acquisitions eliminated the only significant competition
in the market, and resulted in Graco holding a monopoly position as the
only full-line FSE manufacturer. The Order contains provisions,
including prohibitions on discriminating against distributors selling
competitors' FSE products, that are intended to constrain Graco's
ability to exclude prospective entrants into the FSE market by
establishing and/or maintaining exclusive relationships with its third-
party distributors. Commissioner Wright voted in favor of the Complaint
and Order, but also issued a statement outlining his disagreement with
these portions of the Order. We respectfully disagree with Commissioner
Wright, and believe that these specific provisions are necessary to
remediate the anticompetitive impact of the two mergers in this case.
The typical remedy for the Commission in a Section 7 matter is a
divestiture of the illegally acquired assets (and any other assets
necessary to make the divestiture buyer a viable competitor). Pursuing
such a remedy in this matter, however, would be difficult, if not
impossible, because Graco had long ago integrated or discontinued the
product lines it acquired from Gusmer and Glascraft. There was no
easily severable package of assets that could be divested to recreate
one--much less two--viable competitors to replace Gusmer and Glascraft.
As a result, the most effective relief available was a behavioral
remedy intended to facilitate entry into the FSE market, which, of
course, includes addressing the post-acquisition conduct described in
the Complaint that had precluded entry into the relevant market.
Specifically, after the acquisitions Graco solidified its market share
by locking up third-party distributors through a series of purchase and
inventory threshold requirements, as well as threats of retaliation and
termination if distributors carried the products of any remaining or
newly entering FSE manufacturers.
The evidence gathered in the course of the Commission's
investigation demonstrates that Graco's efforts were successful; no
other firm gained more than five percent of the North American FSE
market and Graco's market share of between 90 and 95 percent has
remained intact since its 2008 acquisition of Glascraft. Further, the
investigation uncovered no evidence that Graco's post-acquisition
conduct provided any cognizable efficiency that would benefit
consumers. A remedy that does not address Graco's ability to raise and
maintain nearly insurmountable entry barriers is substantially less
likely to return competition to the FSE market. The Order provisions
that Commissioner Wright criticizes, in our view, are integral to
achieving that goal but will not cause market inefficiencies.
We believe that exclusive dealing relationships can have
procompetitive benefits and that such relationships should not be
condemned in the absence of a thorough factual and economic assessment
of the circumstances surrounding such conduct. But it is equally
important to recognize that, when employed by a competitor that has
acquired significant market power or monopoly power, exclusive dealing
arrangements have the potential to cement such power and prevent or
deter entry that would lead to lower prices, higher quality, and better
service for consumers.\3\ In any event, regardless of how one views
exclusive dealing arrangements generally, there is ample support for
the fencing-in relief prescribed in this merger settlement, which is
designed to restore competition in the FSE market lost as a result of
Graco's illegal acquisitions.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\3\ See, e.g., United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34,
71-72, 74 (D.C. Cir. 2001) (holding that Microsoft's exclusive
dealing arrangements with Internet access providers, independent
software vendors, and Apple violated Sherman Act Sec. 2).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
We join Commissioner Wright in commending the Commission staff for
their hard work in this matter. They have done an excellent job in
investigating the market involved and the issues raised during the
course of this investigation.
By direction of the Commission, Commissioner Wright abstaining.
Donald S. Clark,
Secretary.
Statement of Commissioner Joshua D. Wright
The Commission has voted to issue a Complaint and Order against
Graco, Inc. (``Graco'') to remedy the allegedly anticompetitive effects
of Graco's acquisition of Gusmer Corp. (``Gusmer'') in 2005 and
GlasCraft, Inc. (``GlasCraft'') in 2008. I supported the Commission's
decision because there is reason to believe Graco's acquisitions
substantially lessened competition in the market for fast-set equipment
in violation of Section 7 of the Clayton Act. I want to commend staff
for their hard work in this matter. Staff has conducted a thorough
investigation and developed strong evidence that Graco's acquisition of
Gusmer and GlasCraft likely resulted in higher prices and fewer choices
for consumers.
I write separately to discuss two aspects of the Order with which I
respectfully disagree, namely the provisions prohibiting Graco from
entering into exclusive dealing contracts with distributors and
establishing purchase and inventory thresholds that must be satisfied
in order for distributors to obtain discounts. Both provisions are
aimed at prohibiting exclusivity or, in the case of purchase and
inventory thresholds, loyalty discounts that might be viewed as de
facto exclusive arrangements. I am not persuaded in this case that
prohibiting exclusive dealing contracts and regulating loyalty
discounts will make consumers better off. To the contrary, these
provisions may lead to reduced output or higher prices for consumers. I
therefore do not believe the limitations on such arrangements imposed
by the Order are in the public interest.
I. Appropriate Use of Behavioral Remedies
The majority and I agree that although the most suitable remedy for
an anticompetitive merger usually is a divestiture of assets, under
certain circumstances behavioral remedies may be appropriate.\4\ One
scenario in which behavioral remedies may be appropriate is when the
challenged merger has long since been consummated and divestiture or
other structural remedies are not a viable option for restoring
competition to pre-merger levels. Given that Graco has fully integrated
Gusmer and Glascraft and discontinued their
[[Page 24205]]
product lines, divestiture is not an option and the Commission should
rightly consider whether behavioral remedies in this case would protect
consumers.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\4\ See e.g., Fed. Trade Comm'n, Statement of Federal Trade
Commission's Bureau of Competition on Negotiating Merger Remedies,
at 5 (2012), available at https://www.ftc.gov/bc/bestpractices/merger-remediesstmt.pdf (stating the Commission favors structural
relief, such as divestitures, in horizontal mergers, but that
behavioral relief may be appropriate in some cases).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
As with merger remedies generally, when deciding whether and what
behavioral remedy to impose, the Commission must ultimately be guided
by its mission of protecting consumers.\5\ Because behavioral remedies
displace normal competitive decision-making in a market, they pose a
particularly high risk of inadvertently reducing consumer welfare and
should be examined closely prior to adoption to ensure consumers'
interests are best served. In particular, effective behavioral remedies
must be ``tailored as precisely as possible to the competitive harms
associated with the merger to avoid unnecessary entanglements with the
competitive process.'' \6\ Merely showing high market shares and the
unavailability of structural remedies does not justify restricting
conduct that typically is procompetitive because these conditions do
not make the conduct any more likely, much less generally likely, to be
anticompetitive.\7\ A minimum safeguard to ensure remedial provisions--
whether described as fencing-in relief or otherwise--restore
competition rather than inadvertently reduce it is to require evidence
that the type of conduct being restricted has been, or is likely to be,
used anticompetitively to harm consumers.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\5\ The Commission should keep in mind that ours is not a binary
choice simply between imposing a structural or a behavioral remedy.
The most attractive option from a consumer welfare point of view for
any given circumstance may be to block the merger in its entirety,
allow the merger to proceed without any remedy, or a hybrid solution
combining some aspects of each of these options. Having ruled out
structural remedies in this case, the question is which, if any, of
the non-structural alternatives best improves consumer welfare. See
Ken Heyer, Optimal Remedies for Anticompetitive Mergers, 26
Antitrust 27 (2012) (arguing behavioral remedies are not justified
simply because structural remedies are unavailable, and that an
agency should weigh the economic costs and benefits of each non-
structural alternative, including doing nothing).
\6\ U.S. Dep't of Justice Antitrust Div., Antitrust Division
Policy Guide to Merger Remedies, at 7 n.12 (June 2011), available at
https://www.justice.gov/atr/public/guidelines/272350.pdf; see also,
Heyer, supra note 2, at 27-28 (``[A]mong the most important
considerations in devising a behavioral remedy is that there be a
close nexus between the remedy imposed and the theory of harm
motivating its use.'').
\7\ In fact, efficiencies justifications for exclusive dealing
contracts apply, and some even more strongly, when a firm has market
power.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
With this analytical framework in mind, I support those remedies in
the Order that seek to restore pre-merger competition by imposing
restrictions closely linked to the evidence of anticompetitive harm in
this case. For instance, staff uncovered evidence Graco threatened
distributors that considered carrying fast-set equipment sold by
competing manufacturers, and that these threats actually led to
distributors not purchasing the competing products. Staff also learned
that distributors refused to purchase fast-set equipment from Gama/PMC,
one of the few fringe competitors remaining after Graco's acquisitions,
because of the uncertainty resulting from Graco's lawsuit against Gama/
PMC. The Order thus appropriately prohibits Graco from retaliating
against distributors that consider purchasing fast-set equipment from
other manufacturers \8\ and requires Graco to settle its lawsuit
against Gama/PMC.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\8\ Such retaliatory conduct alone is outside the normal
competitive process and has no plausible procompetitive benefit. Its
proscription therefore is unlikely to harm consumers. Of course, a
decision by Graco to refuse to sell to distributors who do not enter
into an exclusive contract should not itself be proscribed as
illegitimate retaliation.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
In contrast, and as is discussed in more detail below, there is
insufficient evidence linking the remedial provisions in the Order
prohibiting exclusive dealing contracts and regulating loyalty
discounts to the anticompetitive harm in this case.
II. Prohibitions on Exclusive Dealing
It is widely accepted that exclusive dealing and de facto exclusive
contracts--while generally efficiency enhancing--can lead to
anticompetitive results when certain conditions are satisfied. The
primary competitive concern is that exclusive dealing may be used by a
monopolist to raise rivals' costs of distribution by depriving them the
opportunity to compete for distribution sufficient to achieve efficient
scale, and ultimately harm consumers by putting competitors out of
business.\9\ On the other hand, the economic literature is replete with
procompetitive justifications for exclusive dealing, including aligning
the incentives of manufacturers and distributors, preventing free-
riding, and facilitating relationship-specific investments.\10\ In
fact, the empirical evidence substantially supports the view that
exclusive dealing arrangements are much more likely to be
procompetitive than anticompetitive.\11\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\9\ See e.g., Alden F. Abbott & Joshua D. Wright, Antitrust
Analysis of Tying Arrangements and Exclusive Dealing, in Antitrust
Law and Economics 183, 194-96 (Keith N. Hylton ed., 2d ed. 2010).
There also are novel theories of anticompetitive harm, including
models exploring the possibility that certain types of discount
programs effectively impose a tax upon distributors' choice to
expand rivals' sales and thereby potentially prevent rivals from
acquiring a sufficient number of retailers to cover the fixed costs
of entry. See e.g., Joe Farrell, et al., Economics at the FTC:
Mergers, Dominant-Firm Conduct, and Consumer Behavior, 37 (4) Rev.
Indus. Org. 263 (2010).
\10\ See e.g., Abbott & Wright, supra note 6, at 200-01;
Francine Lafontaine & Margaret Slade, Exclusive Contracts and
Vertical Restraints: Empirical Evidence and Public Policy, in
Handbook of Antitrust Economics, 393-94 (Paolo Buccirossi, ed.,
2008); Benjamin Klein & Kevin Murphy, Exclusive Dealing Intensifies
Competition for Distribution, 75 Antitrust L. J. 433, 465 (2008).
\11\ See e.g., Abbott & Wright, supra note 6, at 200-01;
Lafontaine & Slade, supra note 7, at 393-94.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Because exclusive dealing contracts typically are procompetitive
and a part of the normal competitive process, the Commission should
only restrict the use of such arrangements when there is sufficient
evidence that they have or are likely to decrease consumer welfare.
This ensures consumers the merger remedy does not deprive them the
fruits of the competitive process. The evidence in this case is
insufficient to conclude that Graco has used, or intends to use,
exclusive dealing or de facto exclusive contracts to foreclose rivals
and ultimately harm consumers. To the contrary, the Commission's
Complaint describes the fast-set equipment market as one particularly
well suited for exclusive arrangements. Specifically, the Complaint
acknowledges the sale of fast-set equipment demands specialized third
party distributors that possess the technical expertise to teach
consumers how to use and maintain the manufacturer's equipment.\12\ One
could therefore easily imagine that manufacturers might only be willing
to provide training to distributors if they have some assurance that
current or future competitors will be unable to free ride on their
investments in the distributors' technical expertise. Exclusive dealing
arrangements with distributors are one well-known and common method of
preventing such free riding.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\12\ Complaint ] 24, Graco, Inc., FTC File No.101-0215, (April
17, 2013).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The provisions in the Order prohibiting exclusive contracts
therefore may needlessly harm consumers by deterring potentially
procompetitive arrangements. For that reason, I do not believe that
provision is in the public interest.
III. Restrictions on Loyalty Discounts
The primary anticompetitive concerns with loyalty discounts are
analytically similar to those associated with exclusive dealing and de
facto exclusive
[[Page 24206]]
contracts.\13\ As with exclusive dealing, the economic literature also
supports the view that loyalty discounts more often than not are
procompetitive.\14\ The Commission's competition mission therefore is
best served by an approach that counsels against imposing restrictions
on loyalty discounts unless there is sufficient evidence to establish
that such arrangements have or are likely to harm competition and
consumers.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\13\ See generally Bruce H. Kobayashi, The Economics of Loyalty
Discount and Antitrust Law in the United States, 1 Comp. Pol'y Int'l
115 (2005).
\14\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The Order permits Graco to enter into certain loyalty discount
agreements that require distributors to meet annual purchase and
inventory thresholds to qualify for discounted prices.\15\ The Order,
however, restricts the scope of these loyalty discounts by prescribing
the maximum threshold levels Graco may set in 2013 and by only allowing
those maximums to increase by 5 percent year to year. Although there is
evidence that Graco in some instances increased the inventory and
purchase thresholds it required distributors to meet to receive
discounts on fast-set equipment following its acquisitions, I have not
seen evidence sufficient to link these increases to the anticompetitive
effects of the mergers alleged in the Commission's Complaint. For
example, I have seen no evidence that a distributor dropped Gama/PMC or
any other fringe competitor in response to Graco's increased
thresholds. Further, although there appears to be evidence that at
least some distributors are unable to both meet the thresholds
necessary to receive Graco's discounts and carry competing
manufacturers' products, there is nothing barring these distributors
from forgoing those discounts in order to carry multiple products
lines. It has been several years since Graco increased the thresholds.
In the absence of evidence this change harmed competition, the fact
that some distributors prefer to take the discounts is not a sufficient
reason to believe that prohibiting these contracts will protect
consumers. Moreover, it is unlikely that the Commission is best
positioned to gauge what the appropriate threshold should be for each
distributor over time and as market conditions change.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\15\ Decision & Order Sec. III(6)(c), Graco, Inc., FTC File
No.101-0215, (April 17, 2013).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
As a result, based upon the available evidence, I am concerned the
restrictions on loyalty discounts in the Order ultimately may reduce
consumer welfare rather than protect competition. Thus, I do not
believe this aspect of the Order is in the public interest.
* * * * *
For these reasons, I voted in favor of the Commission's Complaint
and Order, but respectfully disagree with the Order provisions
prohibiting exclusive contracts and restricting loyalty discounts. To
the extent the majority believes Graco may use such arrangements to
engage in anticompetitive conduct in the future, the Commission's
willingness and ability to bring a monopolization claim where the
evidence indicates it is appropriate would protect consumers against
the competitive risks posed by these arrangements without depriving
consumers of their potential benefits.
[FR Doc. 2013-09673 Filed 4-23-13; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6750-01-P