Special Access for Price Cap Local Exchange Carriers; AT&T Corporation Petition for Rulemaking To Reform Regulation of Incumbent Local Exchange Carrier Rates for Interstate Special Access Services, 57504-57523 [2012-23020]
Download as PDF
57504
Federal Register / Vol. 77, No. 181 / Tuesday, September 18, 2012 / Rules and Regulations
TABLE 1—GENERAL SUPERFUND SECTION—Continued
State
Site name
City/county
Notes (a)
*
*
*
*
*
Fairfax St. Wood Treaters ............................................................................................................
*
Jacksonville.
*
*
*
*
*
*
Bautsch-Gray Mine ......................................................................................................................
*
Galena.
*
*
*
*
*
*
EVR-Wood Treating/Evangeline Refining Company ...................................................................
*
Jennings.
*
*
*
*
*
*
Leeds Metal ..................................................................................................................................
Leeds.
*
*
*
*
*
Holcomb Creosote Co ..................................................................................................................
*
Yadkinville.
*
*
*
*
*
*
Orange Valley Regional Ground Water Contamination ...............................................................
*
West Orange/Orange.
*
*
*
*
*
*
Peters Cartridge Factory ..............................................................................................................
*
Kings Mills.
*
*
*
*
*
*
West Troy Contaminated Aquifer .................................................................................................
Troy.
*
*
*
*
*
Circle Court Ground Water Plume ...............................................................................................
*
Willow Park.
*
*
*
*
*
*
US Oil Recovery ..........................................................................................................................
*
Pasadena.
*
FL ........
IL ..........
LA ........
ME .......
NC .......
NJ ........
OH .......
OH .......
TX ........
TX ........
*
*
*
*
(a) A = Based on issuance of health advisory by Agency for Toxic Substances and Disease Registry (if scored, HRS score need not be ≤
28.50).
S = State top priority (included among the 100 top priority sites regardless of score).
P = Sites with partial deletion(s).
*
*
*
*
*
[FR Doc. 2012–22851 Filed 9–17–12; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6560–50–P
FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS
COMMISSION
47 CFR Part 1
[WC Docket No. 05–25; RM–10593; FCC 12–
92]
Special Access for Price Cap Local
Exchange Carriers; AT&T Corporation
Petition for Rulemaking To Reform
Regulation of Incumbent Local
Exchange Carrier Rates for Interstate
Special Access Services
Federal Communications
Commission.
ACTION: Final rule.
AGENCY:
In this Report and Order, the
Commission suspends, on an interim
basis, the Commission’s rules allowing
for automatic pricing flexibility grants
for special access services, pending
adoption of new rules. The Commission
suspends its pricing flexibility rules in
light of evidence that the proxies for
measuring actual and potential special
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES
SUMMARY:
VerDate Mar<15>2010
16:24 Sep 17, 2012
Jkt 226001
access market competition, which are
based on collocation by competitive
carriers within a Metropolitan Statistical
Area (MSA), do not accurately predict
whether competition is sufficient to
constrain special access prices and deter
anticompetitive practices by price cap
local exchange carriers. In the Report
and Order, the Commission also
initiates a process to obtain data needed
to conduct a special access market
analysis. Based on this forthcoming data
collection, the Commission will
undertake a robust special access market
analysis to determine the extent to
which the special access market is
competitive and develop special access
pricing flexibility rules to replace the
collocation-based competitive showings.
DATES: Effective October 18, 2012,
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
Jamie Susskind, Wireline Competition
Bureau, Pricing Policy Division, (202)
418–1520 or (202) 418–0484 (TTY), or
via email at Jamie.Susskind@fcc.gov.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: This is a
summary of the Commission’s Report
and Order in WC Docket No. 05–25,
RM–10593, FCC 12–92, adopted on
August 15, 2012 and released on August
22, 2012. The summary is based on the
PO 00000
Frm 00024
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
public redacted version of the
document, the full text of which is
available electronically via the
Electronic Comment Filing System at
https://fjallfoss.fcc.gov/ecfs/ or may be
downloaded at https://transition.fcc.gov/
Daily_Releases/Daily_Business/2012/
db0823/FCC-12-92A1.pdf. The full text
of this document is also available for
public inspection during regular
business hours in the Commission’s
Reference Center, 445 12th Street SW.,
Room CY–A257, Washington, DC 20554.
The complete text may be purchased
from Best Copy and Printing, Inc., 445
12th Street, SW., Room CY–B402,
Washington, DC 20554. To request
alternate formats for persons with
disabilities (e.g. Braille, large print,
electronic files, audio format, etc.) or
reasonable accommodations for filing
comments (e.g. accessible format
documents, sign language interpreters,
CARTS, etc.), send an email to
fcc504@fcc.gov or call the Commission’s
Consumer and Governmental Affairs
Bureau at (202) 418–0530 (voice) or
(202) 418–0432 (TTY).
I. Introduction
1. In this Report and Order, we
suspend, on an interim basis, our rules
E:\FR\FM\18SER1.SGM
18SER1
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES
Federal Register / Vol. 77, No. 181 / Tuesday, September 18, 2012 / Rules and Regulations
allowing for automatic grants of pricing
flexibility for special access services in
light of significant evidence that these
rules, adopted in 1999, are not working
as predicted, and widespread agreement
across industry sectors that these rules
fail to accurately reflect competition in
today’s special access markets. We set
forth a path to update our rules to better
target regulatory relief to competitive
areas, including extending relief to areas
that are likely competitive but have
been denied regulatory relief under our
existing framework. We provide for
targeted relief in the interim through the
forbearance process set forth in sec. 10
of the 1996 Act, and will soon issue a
comprehensive data collection order
that will help craft permanent
replacement rules.
2. Special access continues to play a
critical role in our economy. Four of the
largest incumbent LECs recently
reported that their combined 2010
revenues from sales of DS1s and DS3s
exceeded $12 billion. Competitive
carriers rely heavily on special access to
reach customers; a large competitive
local exchange carrier (LEC) that offers
enterprise services to businesses using
special access services as a critical input
has reported that it purchases
øREDACTED¿ times as many special
access as Ethernet circuits. Enterprise
customers across the country rely on
special access—directly or indirectly—
to conduct their business. Schools,
libraries, and other institutions of state
and local government depend on special
access to provide services to their
constituents.
3. We continue to strongly believe,
consistent with the goals set forth in the
Pricing Flexibility Order, that regulation
should be reduced wherever evidence
demonstrates that actual or potential
competition is acting as a constraint to
ensure just and reasonable rates, terms
and conditions for special access
services. In the record of this
proceeding, however, there is
compelling evidence that our current
pricing flexibility rules are not properly
matching relief to such areas, combined
with allegations that this mismatch is
causing real harm to American
consumers and businesses and
hindering investment and innovation.
Price cap carriers argue that they are
still subject to burdensome regulation in
areas where it is apparent that
competition is thriving. The United
States Small Business Administration
asserts that ‘‘promoting competition in
the business broadband market is
essential in order to provide small
businesses with affordable access and
choice regarding the services they need
to grow and create new jobs.’’ The
VerDate Mar<15>2010
16:24 Sep 17, 2012
Jkt 226001
American Petroleum Institute expresses
concern that, because its member
companies’ facilities are frequently
located in isolated locations where
facilities-based competition is scarce,
they are highly sensitive to incumbent
LECs extracting supra-competitive
profits. Competitive carriers argue that
the terms and conditions of special
access contract tariffs ‘‘lock up’’
demand, preventing competitors from
entering markets and investing in new
facilities. Wireless providers argue that
high special access prices hinder their
ability to hire employees, invest in their
networks, and conduct research and
development. While we cannot yet
evaluate these claims of competitive
harm based on the evidence to date in
the record, our finding that the
competitive showings the Commission
adopted as a proxy for competition are
not working as predicted leads us to
suspend the triggers and further
evaluate the marketplace.
4. The approach we take is based on
our evaluation of our 1999 rules, the
predictive judgments upon which they
were based, and market developments
since their adoption. As discussed in
greater detail below, the Commission
decided in 1999 to use an
administratively simple proxy for the
presence of actual or potential
competition in special access markets—
the extent of collocation within broad
geographic regions. The Commission
predicted that certain levels of
collocation within a Metropolitan
Statistical Area (MSA) would serve as
an accurate indicator of competitive
pressure sufficient to constrain prices
throughout that area.
5. Based on the evidence in the record
and thirteen years of experience with
this regime, we now conclude that the
Commission’s existing collocation
triggers are a poor proxy for the
presence of competition sufficient to
constrain special access prices or deter
anticompetitive practices throughout an
MSA. We therefore suspend, on an
interim basis, the operation of those
rules pending adoption of a new
framework that will allow us to ensure
that special access prices are fair and
competitive in all areas of the country.
6. Although we currently lack the
necessary data to identify a permanent
reliable replacement approach to
measure the presence of competition for
special access services, we emphasize
that the forbearance process set forth by
Congress in the 1996 Act provides an
avenue for targeted relief based on a
complete analysis of competitive
conditions in a geographic area.
7. Going forward, in the absence at
this time of clear evidence to establish
PO 00000
Frm 00025
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
57505
reasonable and reliable proxies to
determine where regulatory relief is
appropriate, we will collect necessary
data and undertake a robust competition
analysis that may identify reliable
proxies for competition in the market
for special access services going
forward. We will issue a comprehensive
data collection order within 60 days to
facilitate this market analysis. We
anticipate that during the pendency of
the data request, we will continue to
analyze the information submitted in
the record, and may issue further
decisions as warranted by the evidence.
Nonetheless, the record in this
proceeding demonstrates that a
comprehensive evaluation of
competition in the market for special
access services is necessary, and that
further data to assist us in that
evaluation is needed with respect to
establishing a new framework for
pricing flexibility.
II. Background
A. History of Price Cap Regulation
8. Through the end of 1990, interstate
access charges were governed by ‘‘rateof-return’’ regulation, under which
incumbent LECs calculated their access
rates using projected costs and projected
demand for access services. An
incumbent LEC was limited to
recovering its costs plus a prescribed
return on investment. It also was
potentially obligated to provide refunds
if its interstate rate of return exceeded
the authorized level. However, a rate of
return regulatory structure bases a firm’s
allowable rates directly on the firm’s
reported costs and was thus subject to
criticisms that it removed the incentive
to reduce costs and improve productive
efficiency.
9. Consequently, in 1991 the
Commission implemented a system of
price cap regulation that altered the
manner in which the largest incumbent
LECs (often referred to today as price
cap LECs) established their interstate
access charges. The Commission’s price
cap plan for LECs was intended to avoid
the perverse incentives of rate-of-return
regulation in part by divorcing the
annual rate adjustments from the cost
performance of each individual LEC,
and provide for sharing efficiency gains
with customers in part by adjusting the
cap based on industry productivity
experience.
10. In contrast to rate-of-return
regulation, which focuses on an
incumbent LEC’s costs and fixes the
profits an incumbent LEC may earn
based on those costs, price cap
regulation focuses primarily on the
prices that an incumbent LEC may
E:\FR\FM\18SER1.SGM
18SER1
57506
Federal Register / Vol. 77, No. 181 / Tuesday, September 18, 2012 / Rules and Regulations
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES
charge. The access charges of price cap
LECs originally were set at levels based
on the rates that existed at the time the
LECs entered the price cap regime.
Increases in their rates have, however,
been limited over the course of price
cap regulation by price indices that are
adjusted annually pursuant to formulae
set forth in Part 61 of our rules. Price
cap regulation is a form of incentive
regulation that seeks to ‘‘harness the
profit-making incentives common to all
businesses to produce a set of outcomes
that advance the public interest goals of
just, reasonable, and nondiscriminatory
rates, as well as a communications
system that offers innovative, high
quality services.’’ A core component of
our price cap regulation is the Price Cap
Index (PCI). As the Commission has
explained previously, the PCI is
designed to limit the prices LECs charge
for service. The PCI provides a
benchmark of LEC cost changes that
encourages price cap LECs to become
more productive and innovative by
permitting them to retain reasonably
higher earnings. The PCI has three basic
components: (1) A measure of inflation,
i.e., the Gross Domestic Product (chain
weighted) Price Index (GDP–PI); (2) a
productivity factor or ‘‘X-Factor,’’ that
represents the amount by which LECs
can be expected to outperform
economy-wide productivity gains; and
(3) adjustments to account for
‘‘exogenous’’ cost changes that are
outside the LEC’s control and not
otherwise reflected in the PCI.
B. Pricing Flexibility
11. Pursuant to the pro-competitive,
deregulatory mandates of the 1996 Act,
the Commission in 1996 began
exploring whether and how to remove
price cap LECs’ access services from
price cap and tariff regulation once they
are subject to substantial competition.
Three years later, in 1999, the
Commission adopted the Pricing
Flexibility Order in an effort to ensure
that the Commission’s interstate access
charge regulations did not unduly
interfere with the operation of interstate
access markets as competition
developed in those markets. The
Commission developed competitive
showings (also referred to as ‘‘triggers’’)
designed to measure the extent to which
competitors had made irreversible, sunk
investment in collocation and transport
facilities. Price cap carriers that
demonstrated the competitive showings
were met in their serving areas could
obtain so-called ‘‘pricing flexibility,’’
namely the ability to offer special access
services at unregulated rates through
generally available and individually
negotiated tariffs (i.e., contract tariffs).
VerDate Mar<15>2010
16:24 Sep 17, 2012
Jkt 226001
The operation of the pricing flexibility
rules is discussed in greater detail in
section 0 below.
C. The CALLS Order
12. In 2000, after a comprehensive
examination of the interstate access
charge and universal service regulatory
regimes for price cap carriers, the
Commission adopted the industryproposed CALLS plan. This plan
represented a five-year interim regime
designed to phase down implicit
subsidies and (as it pertained to
switched and special access charges) to
move towards a more market-based
approach to rate setting. In adopting the
CALLS plan, the Commission offered
price cap carriers the choice of
completing the forward-looking cost
studies required by the Access Charge
Reform Order or voluntarily making the
rate reductions required under the fiveyear CALLS plan. The Commission
permitted carriers to defer the planned
forward-looking cost studies in favor of
the CALLS plan because it found the
plan to be ‘‘a transitional plan that
move[d] the marketplace closer to
economically rational competition, and
it [would] enable [the Commission],
once such competition develops, to
adjust our rules in light of relevant
marketplace developments.’’ All price
cap carriers opted for the CALLS plan.
13. The CALLS plan separated special
access services into their own basket
and applied a separate X-factor to the
special access basket. The X-factor
under the CALLS plan, unlike under
prior price cap regimes, is not a
productivity factor. Rather, it represents
‘‘a transitional mechanism * * * to
lower rates for a specified period of time
for special access.’’ The special access
X-factor was 3.0 percent in 2000 and 6.5
percent in 2001, 2002, and 2003. In
addition to the X-factor, access charges
under CALLS are adjusted for inflation
as measured by the GDP–PI. For the
final year of the CALLS plan (July 1,
2004–June 30, 2005), the special access
X-factor was set equal to inflation,
thereby freezing rate levels. Thus, in the
absence of a new price cap regime postCALLS, price cap LECs’ special access
rates have remained frozen at 2003
levels (excluding any necessary
exogenous cost adjustments). The
Commission hoped that, by the end of
the five-year CALLS plan, competition
would exist to such a degree that
deregulation of access charges (switched
and special) for price cap LECs would
be the next logical step.
PO 00000
Frm 00026
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
D. AT&T’s Petition for Rulemaking and
2005 Special Access NPRM
14. On October 15, 2002, AT&T Corp.
filed a petition for rulemaking
requesting that the Commission revoke
the pricing flexibility rules and revisit
the CALLS plan as it pertains to the
rates that price cap LECs, and the BOCs
in particular, charge for special access
services. AT&T claimed that the
competitive showings required to obtain
pricing flexibility failed to predict priceconstraining competitive entry and,
rather, that significant competitive entry
had not occurred. It further contended
that, based on Automated Reporting
Management Information System
(ARMIS) data, the BOCs’ interstate
special access revenues had more than
tripled, from $3.4 billion to $12.0
billion, between 1996 and 2001 and that
the BOCs’ returns on special access
services were between 21 and 49
percent in 2001. Further, AT&T stated
that, in every MSA for which pricing
flexibility was granted, BOC special
access rates either remained flat or
increased. Thus, AT&T contended both
that the predictive judgment at the core
of the Pricing Flexibility Order had not
been confirmed by marketplace
developments, and that BOC special
access rates exceeded competitive levels
and hence were unjust and
unreasonable in violation of § 201 of the
Communications Act. Because the
predictive judgment had proven wrong,
AT&T asserted, the Commission was
compelled to revisit its pricing
flexibility rules in a rulemaking
proceeding.
15. Price cap LECs generally opposed
the AT&T Petition for Rulemaking. They
claimed that their special access rates
were reasonable and therefore lawful,
that there was robust competition for
special access services, that the
collocation-based competitive showings
were an accurate metric for competition,
and that the data relied upon by AT&T
were unreliable in the context used by
AT&T. SBC noted that AT&T only
provided (and could only provide) data
from a single year (2001) that post-dated
the initial implementation of Phase II
pricing flexibility in 2001, and SBC and
Verizon claimed that ARMIS data were
not designed to evaluate the
reasonableness of rates. The BOCs
contended, moreover, that special
access revenues per line declined
between 1996 and 2001.
16. On January 31, 2005, the
Commission released the Special Access
NPRM. The Special Access NPRM
initiated a broad examination of what
regulatory framework to apply to price
cap LECs’ interstate special access
E:\FR\FM\18SER1.SGM
18SER1
Federal Register / Vol. 77, No. 181 / Tuesday, September 18, 2012 / Rules and Regulations
services following the expiration of the
CALLS plan, including whether to
maintain or modify the Commission’s
pricing flexibility rules for special
access services. As part of our review of
the pricing flexibility rules, which were
adopted, in part, based on the
Commission’s predictive judgment, the
Commission sought to examine whether
the available marketplace data
supported maintaining, modifying, or
repealing these rules. The Commission
noted its commitment to re-examine
periodically rules that were adopted on
the basis of predictive judgments to
evaluate whether those judgments are,
in fact, corroborated by marketplace
developments. Accordingly, the
Commission sought data and comments
on whether actual marketplace
developments supported the predictive
judgments used to support the special
access pricing flexibility rules.
17. The Special Access NPRM also
responded to AT&T’s request for interim
relief. AT&T asked, in addition to
initiating a rulemaking, that the
Commission reinitialize Phase II pricing
flexibility special access rates at an
11.25 percent rate of return, and impose
a temporary moratorium on further
pricing flexibility applications. These
requests were denied; however, the
Commission sought comment on
whether to adopt any interim
requirements in the event that the
Commission was unable to conclude the
NPRM in time for any adopted rule
changes to be implemented in the 2005
annual tariff filings.
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES
E. Recent Actions in the Proceeding
1. Refresh Record
18. In July 2007, the Commission
invited interested parties to update the
record in the special access rulemaking
in light of a number of recent
developments in the industry, including
several ‘‘significant mergers and other
industry consolidation,’’ ‘‘the continued
expansion of intermodal competition in
the market for telecommunications
services,’’ and ‘‘the release by GAO [the
Government Accountability Office] of a
report summarizing its review of certain
aspects of the market for special access
services.’’ While the special access
rulemaking was pending, the
Commission also addressed special
access regulation for price cap carriers
in several other proceedings. A petition
for forbearance from dominant carrier
regulation of enterprise broadband
special access services (i.e., packetbased switched, high-speed
telecommunications services for
businesses) filed by Verizon was
deemed granted in 2006. In orders
VerDate Mar<15>2010
16:24 Sep 17, 2012
Jkt 226001
issued in October 2007 and August
2008, the agency granted petitions filed
by AT&T, Embarq, Frontier, and Qwest
under 47 U.S.C. § 160 seeking similar
forbearance relief, and, in August 2008,
granted Qwest’s petition for similar
relief from regulation of enterprise
broadband special access.
2. Analytical Framework
19. In November 2009, the
Commission sought comment on the
appropriate analytical framework for
examining the issues that the Special
Access NPRM raised. In July 2010, the
Commission’s Wireline Competition
Bureau (Bureau) held a staff workshop
on the economics of special access to
gather further input from interested
parties on the analytical framework the
Commission should use—and the data it
should collect—to evaluate whether the
current special access rules are working
as intended.
3. Voluntary Data Requests
20. In October 2010, the Bureau
issued a public notice inviting the
public to submit data on the presence of
competitive special access facilities to
assist the Commission in evaluating the
issues that the Special Access NPRM
raised. Explaining that data ‘‘would
need to be reviewed’’ before the
Commission could address the issues
raised by the proceeding, the Bureau
asked that the requested data be
submitted by January 27, 2011. The
Bureau also noted that while it
continued to develop an analytical
framework, it would ‘‘ask for additional
voluntary submissions of data in a
second public notice.’’
21. On September 19, 2011, the
Bureau issued a second public notice
requesting the submission of special
access data. In this request, the Bureau
sought detailed data on special access
prices, revenues, and expenditures, as
well as the nature of terms and
conditions for special access services.
The Bureau requested that the data be
submitted to the Commission by
December 5, 2011.
III. The ‘‘Competitive Showings’’
Adopted in 1999 Have Not Worked as
Expected
22. In the Pricing Flexibility Order,
the Commission adopted rules intended
to allow price cap LECs to show, in an
administratively workable way, that
certain parts of the country were
sufficiently competitive to warrant
pricing flexibility for special access
services. As discussed in greater detail
below, we find that the record indicates
that the administratively simple
competitive showings we adopted in
PO 00000
Frm 00027
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
57507
1999 have not worked as intended,
likely resulting in both over- and underregulation of special access in parts of
the country. We therefore suspend the
pricing flexibility competitive showings,
on an interim basis, until we obtain the
requisite data and conduct the market
analysis required to craft replacement
rules.
A. Background
1. Rationale for Competitive Showings
23. In the Pricing Flexibility Order,
the Commission adopted rules that
allow price cap LECs to obtain relief
from pricing regulations as competition
for special access services increased.
The Commission concluded that relief
should be granted in two phases. Phase
I relief permits price cap LECs the
ability to lower their rates through
contract tariffs and volume and term
discounts, but requires that they
maintain their generally available price
cap-constrained tariff rates to ‘‘protect
those customers that lack competitive
alternatives.’’ Phase II relief permits
price cap LECs to raise or lower their
rates throughout an area, unconstrained
by the Commission’s part 61 and part 69
rules.
24. The Commission found that
different levels of collocation in an area
would justify different levels of relief.
Specifically, the Commission held that
Phase I deregulatory relief would be
appropriate in areas where the price cap
LEC was able to show that competitors
had made irreversible, sunk investment
sufficient to ‘‘discourage[e] incumbent
LECs from successfully pursuing
exclusionary strategies,’’ such as
‘‘ ‘locking up’ large customers by
offering them volume and term
discounts.’’
25. The Commission held that Phase
II deregulatory relief would be
appropriate only in areas where a price
cap LEC could show there was a higher
level of collocation—specifically, that
‘‘competitors have established a
significant market presence, i.e., that
competition for a particular service
within the [area] is sufficient to
preclude the incumbent from exploiting
any monopoly power over a sustained
period.’’ That is, competitors would
have ‘‘sufficient market presence to
constrain prices throughout the’’ area
because ‘‘almost all special access
customers have a competitive
alternative’’ and ‘‘[i]f an incumbent LEC
charges an unreasonably high rate for
access to an area that lacks a
competitive alternative, that rate will
induce competitive entry, and that entry
will in turn drive rates down.’’
E:\FR\FM\18SER1.SGM
18SER1
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES
57508
Federal Register / Vol. 77, No. 181 / Tuesday, September 18, 2012 / Rules and Regulations
2. How the Competitive Showings Work
26. Geographic Area of Relief. The
Commission chose to grant pricing
flexibility relief on an MSA basis,
finding that, among the proposed
alternatives ‘‘MSAs best reflect the
scope of competitive entry, and
therefore are a logical basis for
measuring the extent of competition’’
and avoiding the ‘‘increased expenses
and administrative burdens associated
with’’ proposals to grant relief in
smaller geographic areas, such as wire
centers. The Office of Management and
Budget (OMB) defines MSAs as
geographic entities that contain a core
urban area of 50,000 or more
population, and often includes adjacent
counties that have a high degree of
social and economic integration with
the urban core, as measured by
commuting to work. MSAs were
developed not for the purposes of
competition policy, but to meet the
Federal Government’s need to have
‘‘nationally consistent definitions for
collecting, tabulating and publishing
Federal statistics for a set of geographic
areas.’’ OMB may add counties or
principal cities to an MSA, remove
them, or even create new MSAs if
census and population estimates
indicate changes in social and economic
integration between outlying areas and
the urban core.
27. In the Pricing Flexibility Order,
the Commission adopted a list of 306
MSAs based largely on data compiled
from the 1980 census, and froze that list
for use in all pricing flexibility
petitions. Therefore, even if OMB
subsequently expanded the geographic
area of an MSA, a price cap LEC’s grant
of pricing flexibility remains within the
borders of the applied-for MSA. The
Commission also recognized that some
price cap LEC study areas fall outside of
MSA boundaries, and held that it would
‘‘grant price cap LECs pricing flexibility
within the non-MSA parts of a study
area if’’ they were able to make the
required showings ‘‘throughout that
area.’’
28. MSAs can be geographically
extensive and, in many cases, may
encompass areas with vastly different
business density within their borders.
Some illustrative examples include the
Pensacola, Florida MSA and the
Atlanta, Georgia MSA.
29. Proxies for Competitive Showings.
For the sake of administrative
convenience, the Commission adopted
proxies for competition designed to
allow price cap LECs to make the
required showings, ‘‘with a minimum of
administrative burden for the industry
and the Commission.’’ Specifically, the
VerDate Mar<15>2010
16:24 Sep 17, 2012
Jkt 226001
Commission chose to ‘‘rely on
collocation as a proxy for irreversible,
sunk investment’’ in special access
facilities and services. Collocation—as
used in the competitive showing rules—
is an offering by an incumbent LEC
whereby a requesting
telecommunications carrier’s
transmission equipment is located, for a
tariffed charge, at the incumbent LEC’s
central office. The Commission
predicted that collocation by
competitors in incumbent LEC wire
centers would be a reliable indicator of
competition because collocation
typically represented a financial
investment by a competitor to establish
facilities within a wire center. The
Commission predicted that the
collocation-based competitive showings
would ‘‘provide a bright-line rule to
guide the industry’’ and ‘‘an
administratively simple and readily
verifiable mechanism for determining
whether competitive conditions warrant
the grant of pricing flexibility.’’
30. The Commission established
bright line ‘‘triggers’’ based on the
extent of collocation within an MSA
that it expected would allow a price cap
LEC to demonstrate that market
conditions in a given MSA would
warrant relief. Specifically, the
Commission held that price cap LECs
would need to demonstrate
either that (1) competitors unaffiliated with
the incumbent LEC have established
operational collocation arrangements in a
certain percentage of the incumbent LEC’s
wire centers in an MSA, or (2) unaffiliated
competitors have established operational
collocation arrangements in wire centers
accounting for a certain percentage of the
incumbent LEC’s revenues from the services
in question in that MSA. In both cases, the
incumbent also must show, with respect to
each wire center, that at least one collocator
is relying on transport facilities provided by
a transport provider other than the
incumbent LEC.
The specific level of collocation
required varies depending on whether a
price cap LEC is seeking Phase I or
Phase II relief and whether it is seeking
relief for channel terminations or other
special access services.
31. On February 2, 2001, the U.S.
Court of Appeals for the DC Circuit
upheld the Pricing Flexibility Order,
finding that the Commission made a
reasonable policy determination and
sufficiently explained its basis for
adopting the competitive showing
requirements.
PO 00000
Frm 00028
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
B. Subsequent Evidence Undermines the
Commission’s Previous Decision To
Measure Competitive Showings and
Grant Relief on an MSA-Wide Basis and
Justifies Suspension of Rules
1. Original Rationale for Granting
Pricing Flexibility in MSAs and NonMSA Portions of Study Areas
32. The Commission’s 1999 Pricing
Flexibility Order chose MSAs as the
basis for competitive analysis because
the record at the time indicated ‘‘that
MSAs best reflect the scope of
competitive entry, and therefore are a
logical basis for measuring the extent of
competition.’’ The Commission rejected
larger geographic areas such as states
and LATAs ‘‘[b]ecause competitive
LECs generally do not enter new
markets on a statewide basis.’’
Accordingly, ‘‘granting pricing
flexibility over such a large geographic
area would increase the likelihood of
exclusionary behavior by incumbent
LECs, by granting them flexibility in
areas where competitors have not yet
made irreversible investment in
facilities.’’
33. The Commission rejected
concerns from some parties that
‘‘competition may exist in only a small
part of an MSA,’’ finding that ‘‘[t]he
triggers we establish * * * are sufficient
to ensure that competitors have made
sufficient sunk investment within an
MSA.’’ The Commission therefore
rejected smaller geographies, such as
wire centers, concluding that ‘‘the
record does not suggest that this level of
detail justifies the increased expenses
and administrative burdens associated
with these proposals.’’
34. The Commission received little
guidance from commenters on how to
establish an appropriate geographic area
for grants of pricing flexibility in areas
that fall outside of MSAs. In the absence
of such guidance, the Commission
allowed price cap LECs to make a
competitive showing for the entirety of
the non-MSA portions of a study area
for which they sought relief. It decided
against requiring competitive showings
at a more granular level—such as on a
rural service area (RSA) basis, stating
that
* * * we expect competitors to enter MSA
markets first and then to extend their
networks into less densely populated areas.
Because rural areas by definition do not have
large concentrations of population
comparable to urban areas, we expect that
competitive entry into rural areas will be less
concentrated than in urban areas. Therefore,
we do not expect that pricing flexibility will
enable an incumbent to engage successfully
in exclusionary pricing behavior with respect
to one RSA because competitive entry is
limited to another RSA.
E:\FR\FM\18SER1.SGM
18SER1
Federal Register / Vol. 77, No. 181 / Tuesday, September 18, 2012 / Rules and Regulations
The Commission therefore placed more
weight on administrative ease, and
chose to allow price cap LECs to apply
for pricing flexibility for the entirety of
the non-MSA components of a study
area.
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES
2. The Record Now Suggests That Entry
Occurs in Smaller Areas
35. The record in this proceeding
suggests that, contrary to the
Commission’s prediction in 1999, MSAs
have generally failed to reflect the scope
of competitive entry. Rather, in many
instances, the scope of competitive
entry has apparently been far smaller
than predicted.
36. In the sections that follow, we
evaluate whether record evidence
supports the Commission’s prediction
that MSAs and non-MSA sections of
incumbent LEC study areas best reflect
the scope of competitive entry. Entry is
one of the many elements the
Commission and antitrust agencies
analyze when evaluating competition.
As a general principle, firms are likely
to enter a geographic area to compete ‘‘if
the entrant generates sufficient revenue
to cover all costs apart from the sunk
costs of entry. Such entry succeeds in
the sense that the entrant becomes and
remains a viable competitor in the
market.’’ In order to gauge whether
entry would be profitable, firms are
more likely to focus on areas with high
demand for their services, relative to the
cost of providing those services. Our
review of the evidence suggests that
demand varies significantly within any
MSA, with highly concentrated demand
in areas far smaller than the MSA. This
leads us to conclude that competitive
entry is considerably less likely to be
profitable and hence is unlikely to occur
in areas of low demand throughout an
MSA, regardless of whether the MSA
also contains areas with demand at
sufficient levels to warrant competitive
entry. This conclusion is confirmed by
VerDate Mar<15>2010
16:24 Sep 17, 2012
Jkt 226001
the available data, including the record
of pricing flexibility grants since the
Commission’s 1999 Order, and data on
subsequent competitive developments
in these areas.
a. Business Demand Varies Significantly
Within MSAs
37. The Commission sought to define
the geographic areas for which pricing
flexibility requests would be considered
‘‘narrowly enough so that the
competitive conditions within each area
are reasonably similar, yet broadly
enough to be administratively
workable.’’ Our analysis of business
establishment density indicates that
business demand can vary significantly
across an MSA. This suggests that
competitive conditions within an MSA
are also likely to vary significantly,
since areas with higher demand tend to
be more capable of supporting
competition and are more attractive to
potential entrants than low demand
areas. These data provide context for
our analysis of evidence about grants of
pricing flexibility petitions and how
competitive entry has occurred since
adoption of the Pricing Flexibility Order.
38. The plots in Figures 1 and 2 below
illustrate that business demand varies
significantly within MSAs. They show
the distribution of business
establishment density by ZIP code in 12
of the sample of 24 MSAs for which we
sought data in our voluntary data
requests. Figure 1 shows the six MSAs
with the least variance in business
establishment density across ZIP
codes—Fayetteville, North Carolina;
Johnstown, Pennsylvania; Phoenix,
Arizona; Ocala, Florida; GreenvilleSpartanburg, South Carolina; and Lima,
Ohio. The distributions show that, even
within these relatively homogeneous
MSAs, dense pockets of business
establishments exist, as well as areas in
which business establishments are few
and far between. Johnstown,
PO 00000
Frm 00029
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
57509
Pennsylvania is an extremely
concentrated example. In Johnstown,
seventy-five percent of the ZIP codes
(from the minimum observation,
represented by an upside-down ‘‘T’’
shape, to the top of the box) are
clustered near the bottom of the scale
with densities close to zero, while the
remaining twenty-five percent (from the
top of the box to the maximum
observation, represented by a ‘‘T’’
shape) are scattered along the vertical
axis between about five establishments
per square mile and 230 establishments
per square mile. The most dense ZIP
code (15901), which covers the central
business district of Johnstown, is 23
times more dense than the average zip
code in the area. Phoenix is much larger
and somewhat more uniform than
Johnstown, but is nonetheless
characterized by a few very dense ZIP
codes amid a majority of less dense ZIP
codes: while the Phoenix MSA has three
ZIP codes with over 300 establishments
per square mile, over half of the ZIP
codes in the MSA have fewer than 40
establishments per square mile. Overall,
these MSAs are similar in that a small
number of ZIP codes are far more dense
than the rest.
39. The distributions shown in Figure
2 demonstrate more extreme examples
of intra-MSA variance of competitive
conditions. Figure 2 depicts business
establishment density variation for the
six MSAs with the most business
establishment density variation across
ZIP codes: Chicago, Illinois; New
Orleans, Louisiana; New York, New
York; Seattle-Everett, Washington;
Washington, DC; and Los Angeles,
California. Except for New York, half of
the ZIP codes in each MSA contain
fewer than 100 establishments per
square mile, whereas other areas within
each MSA have upwards of 1,000
establishments per square mile.
BILLING CODE 6712–01–P
E:\FR\FM\18SER1.SGM
18SER1
VerDate Mar<15>2010
Federal Register / Vol. 77, No. 181 / Tuesday, September 18, 2012 / Rules and Regulations
16:24 Sep 17, 2012
Jkt 226001
PO 00000
Frm 00030
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4725
E:\FR\FM\18SER1.SGM
18SER1
ER18SE12.070
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES
57510
Federal Register / Vol. 77, No. 181 / Tuesday, September 18, 2012 / Rules and Regulations
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES
40. This variance of competitive
conditions within an MSA is an artifact
of the way MSAs are defined. The
resulting statistical entity can be large,
including the entirety of distant
counties if those counties contain
exurban areas linked to the core by
VerDate Mar<15>2010
16:24 Sep 17, 2012
Jkt 226001
commuting behavior. The Atlanta,
Georgia MSA, for example, includes
Butts County, Georgia (see Figure 3
below). Of the three ZIP codes within
that county, the densest (Jackson,
Georgia 30233) has on average about 2.3
business establishments per square
PO 00000
Frm 00031
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
mile. This contrasts to the density level
of the central business district of
Atlanta’s MSA, which contains
thousands of business establishments
per square mile. This kind of variation
is common across the 12 MSAs we have
examined for these purposes.
E:\FR\FM\18SER1.SGM
18SER1
ER18SE12.071
Billing Code 6712–01–C
57511
Federal Register / Vol. 77, No. 181 / Tuesday, September 18, 2012 / Rules and Regulations
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES
41. Given the foregoing evidence that
MSAs do not have ‘‘reasonably similar’’
competitive conditions across their
geographic areas, and as discussed fully
below, when such competitive
conditions are considered together with
the evidence of how relief has been
granted and how some competitive
entry has occurred, we can no longer
conclude that MSAs ‘‘best reflect the
scope of competitive entry’’ by LECs.
b. Prior Grants of Relief Suggest That
Competitive LEC Entry Occurred at a
Smaller Geographic Level Than the
MSA
42. Though the Commission
acknowledged that demand for special
access services might be concentrated in
certain areas, it designed the
competitive showings with the intent of
ensuring that price cap LECs could not
obtain pricing flexibility throughout an
MSA in instances of extremely
concentrated demand. While
recognizing that ‘‘a few wire centers
may account for a disproportionate
share of revenues for a particular
service,’’ the Commission attempted to
VerDate Mar<15>2010
16:24 Sep 17, 2012
Jkt 226001
set its revenue based collocation triggers
at levels designed to ‘‘ensure that
competitors have extended their
networks beyond a few revenueintensive wire centers.’’ Our analysis
indicates that the 1999 rules have not
effectively fulfilled this intent. This
provides further evidence that MSAs
likely do not reflect the actual scope of
competitive entry.
43. As noted above, the Commission
adopted two types of rules by which
price cap LECs could make the
competitive showings required to obtain
relief. The first type of rule permitted
price cap LECs to obtain relief by
showing the presence of collocators in
a certain percentage of its wire centers
within an MSA. The second type, the
revenue-based rule described above,
reflected the Commission’s concession
that demand for special access services
is often concentrated. Despite this
concession, however, the Commission
cautioned that the revenue-based
threshold for dedicated transport
services would need to be set high
enough ‘‘to ensure that competitors have
extended their networks beyond a few
PO 00000
Frm 00032
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
revenue-intensive wire centers.’’ With
respect to channel terminations to end
users, which the Commission noted
were less competitive than dedicated
transport, it doubled the revenue
requirement for limited pricing
flexibility and increased by almost a
third the requirement for full relief. In
short, the Commission made the
revenue-based rule more difficult to
meet specifically to protect against
grants of pricing flexibility based on
extremely concentrated demand.
44. We have analyzed the 217
incumbent LEC areas for which pricing
flexibility relief for channel
terminations to end users was granted
by order of the Bureau, representing all
such grants associated with pricing
flexibility petitions available in the
Commission’s Electronic Tariff Filing
System. These grants cover 199 MSAs
and five non-MSAs. The majority of
those grants were based exclusively on
the revenue-based rule. Because the
revenue-based rule has different
revenue thresholds for each type of
special access service, the Commission
restricted its analysis to one type,
E:\FR\FM\18SER1.SGM
18SER1
ER18SE12.072
57512
Federal Register / Vol. 77, No. 181 / Tuesday, September 18, 2012 / Rules and Regulations
channel terminations to end users, to
keep the analysis consistent.
45. This analysis shows that our rules
permitted MSA-wide relief on the basis
of extremely concentrated demand in
many instances. For example, as
detailed in the chart below, 72 of the
212 grants for MSAs were based on
revenues of no more than a quarter of
the relevant wire centers within the
MSA. For example, AT&T obtained
Phase II pricing flexibility in the
Pensacola MSA based on the revenues
57513
of three out of 12 wire centers. Further,
30 of those 72 grants were based on the
revenues of only one wire center, 12
were based on the revenues of only two,
and 5 were based on the revenues of
only three.
TABLE 4—MSA-WIDE GRANTS BASED ON EXTREMELY CONCENTRATED DEMAND
Carrier name
Competitive Showing
MSA
Current
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES
Alexandria, LA ..............................................
Anderson, IN .................................................
Anderson, SC ...............................................
Asheville, NC ................................................
Bangor, ME ...................................................
Burlington, NC ..............................................
Columbus, GA-AL .........................................
Evansville, IN-KY ..........................................
Evansville-Henderson, IN-KY .......................
Gainesville, FL ..............................................
Harrisburg, PA ..............................................
Jackson, MI ...................................................
Joplin, MO .....................................................
Kalamazoo, MI ..............................................
Lawton, OK ...................................................
Lima, OH .......................................................
Medford, OR .................................................
Memphis, TN-AR-MS ....................................
Muncie, IN .....................................................
Ocala, FL ......................................................
Owensboro, KY .............................................
Panama City, FL ...........................................
Pittsburgh, PA ...............................................
Pueblo, CO ...................................................
Salem, OR ....................................................
Sioux City, IA-NE ..........................................
St. Cloud, MN ...............................................
St. Joseph, MO .............................................
Waco, TX ......................................................
Waterloo-Cedar Falls, IA ..............................
Battle Creek, MI ............................................
Boise City, ID ................................................
Clarksville-Hopkinsville, TN/KY .....................
Eugene-Springfield, OR ................................
Fargo-Moorehead, ND-MN ...........................
Fort Smith, AR-OK ........................................
Manchester, NH ............................................
Oxnard-Simi Valley-Ventura, CA ..................
Provo-Orem, UT ...........................................
Springfield, IL ................................................
Springfield, MO .............................................
Wilmington, NC .............................................
Augusta, GA .................................................
Bloomington-Normal, IL ................................
Chattanooga, TN-GA ....................................
Pensacola, FL ...............................................
Portland, ME .................................................
46. In sum, more than a third of the
cases in which pricing flexibility was
granted were premised on the existence
of collocations where 65 percent or
more of the special access revenue
generated within the MSA came from 25
percent or fewer of the wire centers in
the MSA. This is consistent with
VerDate Mar<15>2010
16:24 Sep 17, 2012
Jkt 226001
At time of grant
AT&T .........................
AT&T .........................
AT&T .........................
AT&T .........................
Fairpoint ....................
AT&T .........................
AT&T .........................
AT&T .........................
AT&T .........................
AT&T .........................
CenturyLink ...............
AT&T .........................
AT&T .........................
AT&T .........................
AT&T .........................
CenturyLink ...............
CenturyLink ...............
AT&T .........................
AT&T .........................
CenturyLink ...............
AT&T .........................
AT&T .........................
CenturyLink ...............
CenturyLink ...............
CenturyLink ...............
CenturyLink ...............
CenturyLink ...............
AT&T .........................
AT&T .........................
CenturyLink ...............
AT&T .........................
CenturyLink ...............
AT&T .........................
CenturyLink ...............
CenturyLink ...............
AT&T .........................
Frontier ......................
AT&T .........................
CenturyLink ...............
AT&T .........................
AT&T .........................
AT&T .........................
AT&T .........................
Frontier ......................
AT&T .........................
AT&T .........................
Fairpoint ....................
WCs with
collocation
Bell South .................
Ameritech ..................
Bell South .................
Bell South .................
Verizon ......................
Bell South .................
Bell South .................
Bell South .................
Ameritech ..................
Bell South .................
Sprint .........................
Ameritech ..................
SWBT ........................
Ameritech ..................
SWBT ........................
Embarq .....................
Qwest ........................
SWBT ........................
Ameritech ..................
Sprint .........................
Bell South .................
Bell South .................
Sprint .........................
Qwest ........................
Qwest ........................
Qwest ........................
Qwest ........................
SWBT ........................
SWBT ........................
Qwest ........................
Ameritech ..................
Qwest ........................
Bell South .................
Qwest ........................
Qwest ........................
SWBT ........................
Verizon ......................
Pac Bell .....................
Qwest ........................
Ameritech ..................
SWBT ........................
Bell South .................
Bell South .................
Verizon ......................
Bell South .................
Bell South .................
Verizon ......................
extreme variations in business density.
Qualitatively, this suggests that MSAwide grants of pricing flexibility have
encompassed areas in which little or no
competitive entry would be expected.
47. Even with more relaxed standards
for what constitutes extremely
concentrated demand, the data shows
PO 00000
Frm 00033
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
Total WCs
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
3
3
3
3
3
10
5
5
9
14
5
7
4
13
6
14
6
6
8
4
16
7
5
5
10
9
5
14
5
7
8
8
5
14
6
8
8
12
13
8
11
13
9
10
11
12
8
13
20
13
12
22
Percent of
wire centers
with
collocation
10
20
20
11
7
20
14
25
8
17
7
17
17
13
25
6
14
20
20
10
11
20
7
20
14
13
13
20
7
17
25
25
17
15
25
18
15
22
20
18
17
25
23
15
23
25
14
that 97 grants were based on revenues
from less than a third of the wire
centers, and 144 were based on
revenues from less than half of the wire
centers. Conversely, only 28 grants were
based on revenues of two-thirds or more
of the wire centers within the appliedfor MSA.
E:\FR\FM\18SER1.SGM
18SER1
57514
Federal Register / Vol. 77, No. 181 / Tuesday, September 18, 2012 / Rules and Regulations
c. Data Indicates That Competitive LEC
Entry Occurs Only in Areas of High
Business Demand
48. Whereas our bright-line
competitive showings suggested that
some MSAs would soon be, or already
were, competitive more than a decade
ago, recent data indicates that
competitors have a strong tendency to
enter in concentrated areas of high
business demand, and have not
expanded beyond those areas despite
the passage of more than a decade since
the grant of Phase II relief. This provides
further evidence that an MSA is
probably a much larger area than a
competitor would typically choose to
enter.
49. For example, data about the
Atlanta MSA, where BellSouth was
granted Phase II relief in 2000,
demonstrates the importance of
geographic business establishment
density as a driver of competitive entry.
In 2011, staff collected data, on a
voluntary basis, about the presence of
competitive special access facilities for
channel terminations to end users in 24
MSAs. The following providers
submitted data indicating that they
provide facilities-based competition in
parts of the Atlanta MSA: øREDACTED¿.
The first of these carriers is øREDACTED¿,
another is the øREDACTED¿, and three are
among the nation’s øREDACTED¿.
According to those data, only 40 percent
of the ZIP codes in the Atlanta MSA had
competitive access facilities supplied by
even one of the øREDACTED¿ reporting
competitors.
50. The ZIP codes in which the
reporting carriers in Atlanta offered
facilities-based competition were those
with the highest average business
establishment densities. This is
reflected in Table 5, which compares
average business establishment density
between ZIP code areas in which
reporting carriers compete and ZIP
codes areas in which they do not (and
includes similar data for the Miami and
Norfolk MSAs). Because the data
submissions that serve as the basis for
Table 5 were voluntary, the reporting
competitors do not necessarily represent
all competition in the three MSAs
discussed above, and it is possible that
competitors have higher market shares
than our data show. However, Table 5
does not show market shares, but rather
the geographic breadth of coverage by
competitors within the MSA. Further
analysis of these data indicates that the
reporting carriers had a tendency to
enter the same areas within the MSA.
We have no reason to believe that the
competitors’ focus on high business
establishment density indicated by
these data would change if we were able
to obtain data from any other
competitive providers with access
facilities in the Atlanta, Miami and
Norfolk MSAs. Thus, despite the fact
that our competitive showings rules
were designed to predict competitive
entry across an MSA, these data suggest
a strong tendency for competitive LECs
to deploy channel termination facilities
to end users only in ZIP codes with the
highest density of business
establishments.
TABLE 5—AVERAGE BUSINESS ESTABLISHMENT DENSITY IN MSAS BY ZIP CODES WITH VS. WITHOUT FACILITIES-BASED
COMPETITION FROM REPORTING CARRIERS
Number of ZIP
codes in MSA
with reported
facilities-based
competition
MSA and status of incumbent provider
Percent of ZIP
codes in MSA
with reported
facilities-based
competition
Average
establishment
density in ZIP
codes with
reported
facilities-based
competition
(units: estab.
per square
mile)
59
41
36
40
31
78
175
390
106
Atlanta, GA (2000 AT&T/BellSouth Phase II Pricing Flexibility) .....................
Miami, FL (2000 AT&T/BellSouth Phase II) ....................................................
Norfolk, VA (2001 Verizon Phase II) ...............................................................
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES
51. Chart 6 displays the distribution
of establishment density for ZIP codes
in the three MSAs of Table 5. The
distribution at the top of Chart 6 is for
ZIP codes in which no reporting carrier
offered facilities-based competition for
end-user channel terminations and the
distribution at the bottom is for ZIP
codes in which one or more reporting
carriers did offer facilities-based
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:22 Sep 17, 2012
Jkt 226001
competition for end-user channel
terminations. The chart indicates that
the reporting carriers had a greater
tendency to offer competition in ZIP
codes with business establishment
density greater than 100 establishments
per square mile than they did in ZIP
codes with lower establishment
densities. Based on an analysis of the
individual ZIP code areas, the
PO 00000
Frm 00034
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
Average of
establishment
density in ZIP
codes without
reported
facilities-based
competition
(units: estab.
per square
mile)
41
181
59
probability that the carriers’ location
decisions in these metropolitan areas
were not tied to business establishment
density is exceedingly small. The
findings from this analysis are
consistent with other evidence in the
record.
E:\FR\FM\18SER1.SGM
18SER1
52. The fact that there may be other
competitors in these MSAs that are not
reflected in our data, that more
competitors may enter in the future, or
that current competitors may build out
to other parts of the MSA with high
business density does not diminish our
finding that competitors typically enter
in areas of high business establishment
density. Commenters rightly point out
that we do not have comprehensive
facilities data for the MSAs above. We
recognize the limitations of our existing
data set and, as described below, we
intend to collect additional data in the
coming months that will help inform
our analysis. However, even this partial
data provides insight into where
competitors choose to enter within an
MSA, and reinforces evidence we have
received in this record.
53. Incumbent LECs generally
concede that competitors have focused
on areas in which demand for special
access services is very concentrated. As
SBC noted:
Demand for special access services is
highly concentrated in a relatively small
VerDate Mar<15>2010
16:24 Sep 17, 2012
Jkt 226001
number of dense urban wire centers and exurban wire centers containing office parks
and other campus environments. Indeed,
more than [REDACTED] percent of SBC’s
special access demand in Phase II MSAs is
concentrated in [REDACTED] percent of its
wire centers. To meet this demand,
competitors have deployed myriad
competitive facilities—including fiber
connected directly to end-user premises—in
markets across SBC’s territory, particularly in
dense, metropolitan areas and large campus
environments.
Verizon states that more than 80 percent
of demand is generated in 8 percent of
its wire centers, ‘‘enabling competitors
to address a large portion of demand
through targeted investments.’’ This is
consistent with the Commission’s
earlier finding that communities within
an MSA share a center of commerce, but
not necessarily common economic
characteristics relating to
telecommunications deployment. This
record also demonstrates that demand
exists for special access services outside
of these areas and it raises concerns
regarding the availability of competitive
alternatives to meet such demand.
PO 00000
Frm 00035
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
57515
54. Some commenters also allege that
extending new facilities is sufficiently
easy that competitors could reach all
parts of an MSA if warranted even if
they only have facilities in part of an
MSA today. SBC, for example, states
that a large percentage of its demand for
DS1 and DS3 services runs within 1,000
feet, or about three city blocks, of
existing alternative fiber. Thus,
incumbent LECs argue that potential
competition exists throughout an MSA
even if competitive facilities are only
present in a small area. In contrast,
competitive carriers assert that entry is
far more difficult than incumbents
describe in the record. Such
commenters state that, as compared to
incumbent providers who have
achieved economies of scope and scale
in the provision of telecommunications
services, it is not economical for
competitors to deploy their own
facilities to serve all special access
demand. Competitive carriers note that
construction costs, the costs of fiber and
electronics, backhaul costs, transaction
costs involved in negotiating with
E:\FR\FM\18SER1.SGM
18SER1
ER18SE12.073
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES
Federal Register / Vol. 77, No. 181 / Tuesday, September 18, 2012 / Rules and Regulations
57516
Federal Register / Vol. 77, No. 181 / Tuesday, September 18, 2012 / Rules and Regulations
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES
suppliers, and other recurring costs
such as rent, utilities, and maintenance
are typically too large to justify
provisioning a building with relatively
low levels of demand. Covad and XO,
for example, estimate the costs of
deploying a building lateral to be
[REDACTED], and tw telecom estimates
that [REDACTED]. Commenters, including
Covad, XO, BT Americas, and tw
telecom, also point to important barriers
to entry, including the delays in or
impossibility of securing municipal
franchise agreements, rights-of-way
agreements, building access agreements,
and building and zoning permits.
55. We need not resolve this
controversy here, however, for data
provided by incumbent LECs
demonstrate that, even if competitors
could easily deploy fiber to serve
customer demand within 1,000 feet of
incumbents’ facilities, many parts of an
MSA would still not be served by
competitive fiber. For instance, a 2007
AT&T map depicting competitive fiber
deployment in the Austin, Texas MSA
appears to indicate that, out of the 24
AT&T wire centers in the MSA,
competitive fiber does not extend to
[REDACTED]. Maps submitted by SBC in
2005 provide similar data. For instance,
SBC estimates that in the San Diego
MSA, [REDACTED]. This cuts against
assertions that the majority of special
access demand could be easily and
quickly served by proximate
competitive alternatives.
d. Analysis of Multi-Incumbent LEC
MSAs Also Suggests That MSAs Do Not
Correspond to the Scope of Entry
56. As discussed above, the
Commission selected the MSA because
it decided the MSA best reflected the
scope of competitive entry. If our rules
operated in a manner consistent with
our predictions, it should follow that
uniform relief would generally be
granted when two or more price cap
LECs operate in the same MSA. That has
not proven to be the case. For example,
in the Evansville, Indiana MSA,
BellSouth has 4 wire centers and
Ameritech has 13. In 2001, Ameritech
qualified for Phase I pricing flexibility.
In contrast, BellSouth met the higher
competitive showings requirements for
Phase II pricing flexibility one year
later. Likewise, in 2002, Verizon
satisfied the requirements for Phase II
pricing flexibility for its 2 wire centers
in the Bridgeport-Stamford-Norwalk,
Connecticut MSA. Two years later,
SNET was only able to get Phase I
pricing flexibility, based on revenue of
9 out of its 22 wire centers in the same
MSA. In the total of 12 MSAs in which
we granted pricing flexibility to more
VerDate Mar<15>2010
16:24 Sep 17, 2012
Jkt 226001
than one provider within the MSA, our
data shows instances of inconsistent
grants of pricing flexibility in nine.
These data reinforce our conclusion that
competitive conditions can vary
significantly across an MSA.
e. Billing Practices May Not Be
Indicative of Competitive Entry
57. It is not clear, based on our
existing record, that incumbent LEC
billing practices lead to consistent
pricing across an MSA. Commenters, in
particular incumbent LECs, argue that
special access pricing is generally not
tied to a small geographic market, but
rather pricing is uniform throughout an
MSA or larger geographic region. Thus,
because tariffs typically encompass an
MSA or larger geographic region,
incumbents assert that prices are
constrained across that whole area,
regardless of the presence of
competition in any individual location.
Such commenters also argue that it is
administratively burdensome for the
Commission to assess whether
competition exists for granular
geographic markets, and that it would
be onerous for carriers to implement
pricing flexibility for individual
buildings or wire centers. Thus, AT&T,
for example, states that the current
pricing flexibility rules strike ‘‘a
reasonable balance between the costs
and benefits of identifying with greater
granularity those geographic areas
where LECs face competition from rivals
with sunk investments and the
administrative manageability of pricing
flexibility rules.’’
58. There also is evidence, however,
that incumbent LEC billing practices
may not be uniform across MSAs. Price
cap LECs have the authority to set prices
in zones within an MSA or the nonMSA portions of a study area. In the
Pricing Flexibility Order, the
Commission amended § 69.123 of its
rules to permit incumbent price cap
LECs to deaverage geographically their
rates for access services in the trunking
basket, and to allow price cap
incumbent LECs to define the scope and
number of density zones. The
Commission noted that ‘‘averaging
across large geographic areas distorts the
operation of markets in high-cost areas
because it requires incumbent LECs to
offer services in those areas at prices
substantially lower than their costs of
providing those services.’’ However, by
granting incumbent LECs the flexibility
to ‘‘choose the number of zones and the
criteria for establishing zone
boundaries, they are more likely to
establish reasonable and efficient
pricing zones.’’ The record indicates
that price cap LECs do, in at least some
PO 00000
Frm 00036
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
cases, take advantage of § 69.123’s
geographic deaveraging provisions. It is
therefore possible for price cap LECs to
charge different prices in, for example,
rural and urban areas within an MSA or
non-MSA portion of a study area, and
the record indicates that carriers may
engage in this practice.
59. Moreover, in Phase I and Phase II
pricing flexibility areas, carriers can and
do offer contract tariffs to special access
customers on an individualized basis.
The record indicates that such contract
terms are rarely, if ever, adopted by
other special access purchasers. Thus,
whether special access pricing is, in
fact, disciplined across a broad
geographic area as claimed by
incumbent LECs remains an open
question.
f. Changes to MSAs Impact Non-MSA
Rules
60. Price cap LECs seeking pricing
flexibility under our rules in a non-MSA
area must make competitive showings
throughout the entire non-MSA portion
of a study area, rather than a Rural
Service Area or smaller geography. The
Commission justified its adoption of the
non-MSA as the appropriate geographic
area because it predicted that
‘‘competitive entry into rural areas
[would] be less concentrated than in
urban areas.’’ Embarq contends that our
decision to use the non-MSA parts of a
study area, instead of an RSA, has made
it impossible for Embarq to obtain relief
in Missouri despite the presence of
competition. Though Embarq’s situation
may be indicative of a problem specific
to our choice of adopting the non-MSA,
any changes we find to be warranted
with respect to the MSA, as discussed
above, must be reflected by
corresponding changes to non-MSA
areas.
61. Moreover, the record in this
proceeding suggests that the Pricing
Flexibility Order’s prediction that
competition in rural areas would not be
concentrated was incorrect. A review of
our grants of pricing flexibility for
channel terminations to end users in
non-MSA areas highlights problems
similar to what we found in MSA areas.
Specifically, out of five of these types of
grants, three were based on high
concentrations of demand. Verizon’s
grant in non-MSA Idaho was based on
the revenues of 3 out of 26 wire centers,
and its grant for non-MSA West Virginia
was based on revenues from 8 out of 97
wire centers. A third grant, from ACS,
was based on revenues from only half of
the wire centers in non-MSA Juneau,
Alaska. This suggests that, at the time
the grant of pricing flexibility was made,
competitive conditions varied greatly
E:\FR\FM\18SER1.SGM
18SER1
Federal Register / Vol. 77, No. 181 / Tuesday, September 18, 2012 / Rules and Regulations
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES
within the non-MSA areas. Even if new
competitors subsequently entered the
non-MSA, for the reasons discussed
above with respect to MSAs, they are
likely to locate only in areas of high
demand. Thus, the evidence in this
proceeding suggests highly concentrated
competitive conditions at the time
pricing flexibility was granted. This
indicates that the Pricing Flexibility
Order’s prediction that competition in
non-MSA areas would be less
concentrated than in urban areas may
have been incorrect.
3. The Competitive Showings Are Not as
Administratively Simple as Expected
62. In addition to the issues identified
above, our experience shows that our
rules, which were intended first and
foremost to be straightforward and
simple to administer, are not.
Specifically, in adopting the Pricing
Flexibility Order, the Commission
concluded that using MSA-based rules
would be simpler and less expensive to
administer than rules based on other
geographies or regimes that might create
a ‘‘more finely-tuned picture of
competitive conditions.’’ However, the
rules have not been as administratively
simple or easy to verify as the
Commission anticipated, nor does it
appear that they have provided brightline guidance to industry. We therefore
choose to redirect our efforts to
conducting a more complete market
analysis, as discussed in greater detail
in Section 0 below.
63. Previous pricing flexibility
petitions demonstrate that our rules
have failed to provide a clear-cut guide
to industry. For example, § 22.909(a) of
our rules define MSAs for pricing
flexibility, as ‘‘* * * 306 areas * * *
defined by the Office of Management
and Budget, as modified by the FCC.’’
Because OMB changes the list of MSAs
and component counties, as discussed
above, § 22.909 of the Commission’s
rules refers to a static list, based on data
from the 1980 Census. Nonetheless, the
fact that our rules refer to areas in which
to make a competitive showing as
‘‘MSAs’’ has apparently created some
confusion among petitioners, resulting
in petitions containing data calculated
over different MSA definitions. For
example, Pacific Bell submitted a
petition for pricing flexibility in the San
Diego and Sacramento MSAs based on
the list referenced in § 22.909 of our
rules. In contrast, Embarq and
Cincinnati Bell based their 2007 pricing
flexibility petitions on MSAs drawn in
accordance with a ‘‘Metropolitan Areas
(1993)’’ map, located on the
Commission’s Web site, that provides a
detailed description of how the map
VerDate Mar<15>2010
16:24 Sep 17, 2012
Jkt 226001
includes MSAs as defined by OMB.
However, because the 1993 MSAs were
more recently constructed and based on
1990 Census data, the component
counties that make up each MSA are
often different from those in the MSA
list referenced in § 22.909 of our rules.
Thus, our supposedly bright-line rules
have failed to provide guidance to
sophisticated firms such as Embarq and
Cincinnati Bell.
64. Moreover, our competitive
showings are ambiguous and require
time-intensive review and policy
decisions by Commission staff. In order
to fulfill the requirements of the
revenue-based competitive showings, a
petitioner must: (a) Provide a list of wire
centers within that MSA; and (b)
calculate revenues based on that
number. However, our rules do not
specify how to determine whether a
wire center belongs to a specific MSA,
nor do they provide enough specifics as
to what revenues should be included.
Therefore, as applied, petitioners are
making these determinations using
different methodologies. For example,
Southwestern Bell determined which
wire centers belonged to the Amarillo
and St. Louis MSAs based on ‘‘the
Collocation Implementation,
Collocation Point of Contact and
Tracking Database,’’ which includes
wire center information for all MSAs. It
excluded from its revenue calculations
those revenues derived from Individual
Case Basis (ICB) arrangements, i.e., ‘‘the
carrier practice of providing a particular
service in response to a specific request
from a customer under individualized
rates, terms, and conditions.’’ An ICB
arrangement may involve services
directly related to the provision of
special access services, such as special
conditioning of a line. In contrast, in a
2008 petition, Windstream
acknowledged that some of its wire
centers located outside the applied-for
MSA may serve locations inside the
MSA boundary. Therefore, based on its
own engineering maps, ‘‘Windstream
calculated the exchange area that fell
within the MSA. If the area calculated
exceeded 50 percent of the total area of
the wire center, the wire center was
assigned to the MSA.’’ In contrast to
Southwestern Bell’s system of
calculating revenues, Windstream
included ICB revenues in its revenue
calculations. Thus, in order to properly
evaluate whether these petitioners have
fulfilled the requirements of our rules,
which are silent on these issues,
Commission staff would have to do a
thorough review of the company’s
internal records, exercise an extensive
amount of independent judgment, and
PO 00000
Frm 00037
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
57517
make some significant policy decisions
as to whether each company’s
interpretation of our rules are consistent
with the terms of the Pricing Flexibility
Order.
C. Shortcomings of Competitive
Showings Based Exclusively on
Collocation
65. Significant questions also exist
about the reliability of collocation as a
proxy for facilities-based competition in
end user channel terminations. Charges
for special access generally are divided
into channel termination charges and
channel mileage charges. Channel
termination charges recover the costs of
facilities between the customer’s
premises and the LEC end office and the
costs of facilities between the IXC POP
and the LEC serving wire center.
Channel mileage charges recover the
costs of facilities (also known as
interoffice facilities) between the
serving wire center and the LEC end
office serving the end user. In the
Pricing Flexibility Order, the
Commission found that pricing
flexibility for channel terminations
between a LEC end office and a
customer premises required a higher
threshold showing than pricing
flexibility for other dedicated transport
and special access services. In reaching
this determination, the Commission
acknowledged that the economics of
channel terminations between the LEC
office and the customer premises make
it more costly for new entrants to
compete in that product market.
1. Rationale for Adopting Collocation as
the Sole Indicator of Competition
66. The competitive showings require
price cap LECs to offer evidence of
collocation by ‘‘competitors that use
transport provided by a transport
provider other than the incumbent LEC’’
for granting pricing flexibility for
special access and dedicated transport.
The Commission considered that the
competitive showings reasonably
balanced two goals: ‘‘(1) Having a clear
picture of competitive conditions in the
MSA, so that we can be certain that
there is irreversible investment
sufficient to discourage exclusionary
pricing behavior; and (2) adopting an
easily verifiable, bright-line test to avoid
excessive administrative burdens.’’ The
Commission found that collocation was
a ‘‘reliable indicator of sunk investment
by competitors’’ in dedicated transport
and special access services other than
channel terminations because it
demonstrated a financial investment by
the competitor in establishing facilities
in that wire center.
E:\FR\FM\18SER1.SGM
18SER1
57518
Federal Register / Vol. 77, No. 181 / Tuesday, September 18, 2012 / Rules and Regulations
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES
67. With respect to channel
terminations, the Commission
acknowledged that ‘‘collocation by
competitors does not provide direct
evidence of sunk investment by
competitors in channel terminations
between the end office and the customer
premises.’’ Indeed, the Commission
recognized that ‘‘a competitor
collocating in a LEC end office
continues to rely on the LEC’s facilities
for the channel termination between the
end office and the customer premises, at
least initially, and thus is susceptible to
exclusionary pricing behavior by the
LEC.’’ The Commission predicted,
however, that ‘‘that a new market
entrant would provide channel
terminations through collocation and
leased LEC facilities only on a
transitional basis and [would]
eventually extend its own facilities to
reach its customers.’’ It thus concluded
that despite ‘‘the shortcomings of using
collocation to measure competition for
channel terminations, * * * it appears
to be the best option available to us at
this time.’’
2. More Recent Evidence Suggests That
Collocation May Produce an Unreliable
Picture of Competitive Conditions
68. Evidence submitted to the
Commission since 1999 calls into
question the Commission’s prediction
that collocators would eventually build
their own channel terminations to end
users. By the end of 2005, six years after
the adoption of the Pricing Flexibility
Order, SBC Communications, Inc. (SBC)
had obtained pricing flexibility for
channel terminations to end users in 67
MSAs. That same year, it acquired
AT&T Corporation. Both the
Commission and the Antitrust Division
of the U.S. Department of Justice (‘‘the
Division’’) approved the transaction,
subject to several concessions, including
divestitures. Despite SBC’s success in
obtaining pricing flexibility in many
MSAs, the Division’s antitrust
investigation concluded that ‘‘for the
vast majority of commercial buildings in
its territory, SBC is the only carrier that
owns a last-mile connection to the
building.’’ That same year, the
Commission’s review of Qwest’s
petition for forbearance in Omaha,
Nebraska showed that some buildout to
end users had occurred, but only in 9
out of 24 of Qwest’s wire centers in the
Omaha MSA. This was three years after
Qwest had obtained Phase II pricing
flexibility in the Omaha MSA, based on
the revenues of 11 wire centers (8 of
which overlapped with the 9 wire
centers with buildout to end users). In
2006, the U.S. Government
Accountability Office (‘‘GAO’’) analyzed
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:22 Sep 17, 2012
Jkt 226001
16 metropolitan areas in which the
Commission had granted pricing
flexibility and found that facilitiesbased competitors served fewer than 6
percent of buildings with at least a DS1level of demand. In 2010, Qwest noted
in its transfer of control application
with CenturyLink that ‘‘it is Qwest’s
practice generally to use the facilities of
other carriers when it sells services to
enterprise customers in locations
outside of its service territory.’’
69. Commenters’ pleadings also
suggest that collocation has not always
developed into facilities-based
competition. As evidence to support its
assertion that our predictions about
collocation were inaccurate, TW
Telecom relied on data supplied by
Verizon to assert that between 1996 and
2004, non-incumbent LEC channel
termination buildout to commercial
buildings increased from 24,000
buildings to approximately 31,467
buildings (a change of 7,467), in contrast
to the ‘‘millions of buildings served by
incumbent LEC fiber.’’ In 2005, WilTel
estimated that competitors had
deployed to 25,000 buildings, whereas
Sprint asserted in 2007 that only 22,000
buildings had competing connections.
Moreover, TW Telecom states that, as of
a 2003 Commission finding, competitors
serve only three to five percent of
commercial buildings nationwide. It
also submitted evidence that it contends
shows that, four years after Verizon had
obtained Phase I pricing flexibility in
the New York MSA for channel
terminations to end users, competitors
served fewer than øREDACTED¿ of
220,000 buildings in New York City. Its
evidence also showed that, in Chicago,
where Ameritech had obtained pricing
flexibility for channel terminations in
2003, competitors connected to only 429
out of 241,000 commercial buildings.
70. Commenters also argue that the
mere installation of third party facilities
within wire centers does not equate to
competition by collocators because in
some cases they are not being used to
provide competitive service. For
example, in its oppositions to two
incumbent LEC petitions for pricing
flexibility, AT&T argued that it never
used the facilities it had installed in
some of the wire centers listed in the
petitions, and it was therefore
erroneously identified as a competitive
collocator. However, the competitive
showing rules do not require incumbent
LECs to show that collocation facilities
are being used, but only that they exist
in the wire center. Moreover, Sprint
argues that collocation ‘‘is indicative not
that the competitor has placed its own
facilities into buildings but rather that it
PO 00000
Frm 00038
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
has dependence upon the incumbent’s
facility.’’
71. We acknowledge that this
evidence is limited. The Commission’s
recent attempts to obtain more robust
facilities data through voluntary
production have provided useful, but
incomplete, data. Nonetheless, the
evidence we do have suggests our
predictions were inaccurate and that the
accuracy of the use of collocations as a
proxy for actual or potential
competition warrants further
investigation. We therefore intend to
issue a data request that will require
carriers to submit the data we need to
test the accuracy of the predictions we
made about collocation in the Pricing
Flexibility Order.
3. Existence of Non-Collocation Based
Competition Does Not Undercut the
Need To Suspend Grants of New Pricing
Flexibility Petitions
72. Several commenters argue that
relying exclusively on collocation is
flawed because it undercounts entry by
non-collocating firms who have built
their own facilities. We agree, but
because we lack reliable data on the
extent or location of this competition, it
does not change our conclusion that
new pricing flexibility petitions should
be suspended at this time.
73. Several commenters discuss
growing competition from noncollocating competitors, such as cable.
For example, Verizon claims that the
competitive showings preclude it from
obtaining pricing flexibility
commensurate to the level of
competition they claim exists in Los
Angeles, Boston, New York,
Philadelphia, and Washington, DC,
because our rules do not account for
several non-collocating firms that
Verizon’s research indicates have
operations in those areas. AT&T has
similar complaints for its operations in
Chicago, Dallas, Houston, Detroit, San
Diego and St. Louis, contending that it
has lost special access business to cable
firms in many instances. Embarq asserts
that it too has lost business to a
competitive LEC, Cox Cable, that does
not collocate in Las Vegas, Nevada, and
Fort Walton Beach and Ocala, Florida.
Price cap LECs also criticize the rules
for excluding competitors that collocate
at ‘‘collocation hotels,’’ as opposed to
price cap LEC wire centers. Thus, the
record indicates that at times the rules
may prevent price cap LECs from
obtaining partial or full pricing
flexibility because they do not account
for competition sufficient to discipline
rates from facilities-based competitors.
74. We agree. As the Commission
stated when it adopted its competitive
E:\FR\FM\18SER1.SGM
18SER1
Federal Register / Vol. 77, No. 181 / Tuesday, September 18, 2012 / Rules and Regulations
showings rules, it has ‘‘long recognized
that it should allow incumbent LECs
progressively greater pricing flexibility
as they face increasing competition’’
and wanted to ensure that its
‘‘regulations do not unduly interfere
with the development and operation of
these markets as competition develops.’’
It would be inconsistent with this
approach if we inappropriately
subjected price cap LECs to unnecessary
regulations, despite the emergence of
competition that bright-line rules are
unable to detect. We therefore agree to
undertake a robust competition analysis
that takes these factors into account, as
described below.
75. Moreover, there is currently no
evidence in the record addressing the
relationship, if any, between collocation
levels and the presence of noncollocated competitors. Such data
would assist in testing incumbents’
claims that they have lost business to
non-collocating competitors with their
own fiber. We intend to obtain evidence
on this point in order to conduct the
robust competition analysis described
below.
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES
IV. Grants of Pricing Flexibility Are
Suspended
76. As set forth in sections 0 and III.C
above, there is compelling evidence that
the competitive showings adopted in
1999 have not worked as intended, and
that our pricing flexibility rules are
simultaneously preventing grants of
pricing flexibility in areas that likely are
competitive and allowing grants of
pricing flexibility in areas where it is
not appropriate to do so. While we
today initiate the process of developing
a better way to identify areas where
special access regulatory relief is
appropriate, it would not serve the
public interest to allow continued grants
of pricing flexibility under our old rules.
We therefore act in this section to
temporarily suspend the operation of
our competitive showing rules pending
completion of our inquiry.
A. Suspension of Competitive Showing
Rules for Channel Terminations
77. Based on the evidence in the
record as discussed in subsections 0 and
III.0 above, we suspend further grants of
pricing flexibility on the basis of our
existing pricing flexibility rules.
Generally, the Commission’s rules may
be suspended for good cause shown. In
light of the significant problems
identified with grants of regulatory
relief at the MSA level, continuing to
grant relief under the current framework
would run precisely the risk that the
Commission sought to avoid in the
Pricing Flexibility Order: ‘‘Granting
VerDate Mar<15>2010
16:24 Sep 17, 2012
Jkt 226001
pricing flexibility over such a large
geographic area would increase the
likelihood of exclusionary behavior by
incumbent LECs by giving them
flexibility in areas where competitors
have not yet made irreversible
investment in facilities.’’ Given our
finding that the special access pricing
flexibility triggers are not operating as
predicted by the Commission, our
action here suspending the application
of those rules while we consider
possible new regulatory approaches is
necessary in the public interest. In
addition, it is consistent with our
‘‘continuing obligation to practice
reasoned decision making’’ under the
APA. Indeed, this continuing obligation
to practice reasoned decision making
and revisit our rules is especially
relevant where our predictive judgments
do not materialize. The record indicates
that the 1999 competitive showing rules
are both over-inclusive and underinclusive, thereby resulting in grants of
pricing flexibility to broad geographic
areas (i.e., MSAs) based on small
pockets of concentrated demand, or
denials of pricing flexibility where
competitive alternatives are not
recognized by the existing rules.
Moreover, there is evidence that
collocations—while perhaps ‘‘the best
option available’’ to the Commission at
the time—are not a reliable indicator of
the presence of actual or potential
competition in the provision of channel
terminations.
78. The Commission’s rules provide
that petitions for pricing flexibility for
special access services that are not
denied within 90 days after the close of
the pleading cycle are deemed granted.
Given the significant problems
identified with our existing pricing
flexibility rules discussed above, we
find that it would be inappropriate to
allow new grants of flexibility under
those rules. Thus, pursuant to rule § 1.3,
we find good cause to suspend the 90
day deadline in rule § 1.774(f)(1) and do
so on our own motion. We therefore
amend our rules as set forth in
Appendix A.
B. Suspension of Competitive Showing
Rules for Non-Channel Termination
Special Access
79. As noted above, the staff analysis
of specific data highlighting problems
with the MSA was restricted to channel
terminations to end users. Nonetheless,
the record also indicates a lack of
‘‘reasonably similar’’ competitive
conditions within an MSA for dedicated
transport. As discussed above, both
Verizon and SBC concede that special
access demand—for all categories of
special access services—is extremely
PO 00000
Frm 00039
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
57519
concentrated. Fiber maps that they
submitted throughout this proceeding,
which include both dedicated transport
and channel terminations, highlight that
fact. In 2007, AT&T submitted detailed
maps showing competitive deployment
for Atlanta, Georgia; Miami, Florida;
Columbus, Ohio; Austin, Texas and San
Jose, California. In 2012, it submitted
competitive deployment maps for three
of those same MSAs (Atlanta, Miami
and San Jose), as well as several other
MSAs. Though each of those maps—
whether they were produced in 2007 or
2012—display competitive fiber in the
central portion of each MSA, none of
those maps show that those competitive
fibers reach throughout the MSAs. In
addition, as discussed above with
respect to our review of pricing
flexibility grants for channel
terminations for end users, in a
significant number of the MSAs where
price cap carriers have been granted
relief, a large proportion of wire centers
have either no collocations, no
competitive transport, or both. This
calls into question whether our
transport bright-line tests, which if met
lead to pricing flexibility being applied
to the entire MSA, appropriately
distinguish where competition exists
and where it does not. Further, though
the Pricing Flexibility Order noted
competitive differences among special
access services, it did not make any
distinctions as to the appropriate
geographic area of relief based on the
type of service at issue. Instead, the
Commission adopted bright-line
competitive showings, with a uniform
geographic area, for all categories of
special access service. For these reasons,
we find it appropriate to temporarily
suspend our competitive showing rules
for dedicated transport.
C. Arguments Against Suspension of
Rules
80. Broad Assertions Regarding
Competition. Commenters assert that the
deregulatory approach of pricing
flexibility, as well as the current
competitive showing rules, has been
sufficient to constrain exclusionary or
predatory conduct by LECs to date. For
example, Verizon, Qwest, AT&T, and
CenturyLink assert that special access
prices have fallen since the adoption of
pricing flexibility, and that special
access outputs have increased.
CenturyLink states that special access
must be considered in the broader
context, as incumbent LECs have been
facing substantial business challenges.
Thus, absent evidence of a fundamental
failure in the current pricing flexibility
rules—which commenters believe has
not been shown in the record—the
E:\FR\FM\18SER1.SGM
18SER1
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES
57520
Federal Register / Vol. 77, No. 181 / Tuesday, September 18, 2012 / Rules and Regulations
Commission should not substantially
revise or eliminate those rules.
81. There is insufficient evidence in
the record upon which to base general
or categorical conclusions regarding the
competitiveness of the special access
market. As an initial matter, it is not
clear how the Commission should
consider arguments that market
definitions are not relevant because the
undefined market is highly competitive.
Such arguments would have us presume
the outcome at the heart of our inquiry
prior to conducting any analysis of
market conditions. Categorical
assertions about competitiveness are not
an adequate basis upon which we can
base grants of pricing flexibility,
particularly in light of the problems
with the current competitive showing
requirements, as well as the potentially
conflicting evidence in the record about
the changes in special access prices in
Phase I and Phase II pricing flexibility
areas. While incumbent LECs assert that
special access prices have fallen in
pricing flexibility areas, competitors
state that prices, particularly in areas
granted Phase II relief, have increased.
This evidence is inconclusive; thus, we
do not pass judgment on these
assertions in this Report and Order.
However, given the problems associated
with the 1999 competitive showing
rules, we do believe that the record
contains sufficient disputed evidence to
warrant further scrutiny by the
Commission. The current competitive
showing rules provide only a limited
inquiry into the state of competition in
a given market, a fact that commenters,
including incumbent LECs, concede.
82. Moreover, we do not agree that
WorldCom or the Pricing Flexibility
Order compel us to maintain the
collocation-based competitive showing
rules or a similar standard. In
WorldCom, the court explicitly affirmed
the Commission’s discretion to adopt
new policy positions, provided that it
provides a reasoned analysis to support
its decisions. Further, the WorldCom
court noted that, unless they are
statutorily precluded from doing so,
agencies have the discretion to make
adjustments to their regulations in light
of changed circumstances. The court
also held that the Commission did not
err in basing its policymaking on
‘‘predictive forecasts,’’ because the
Commission’s adoption of the
competitive showing rules was a
reasonable prediction of how
competition for special access might
develop in the future. Throughout this
Report and Order, we identify the
problems associated with the current
pricing flexibility rules and explain why
suspending the current competitive
VerDate Mar<15>2010
16:24 Sep 17, 2012
Jkt 226001
showings while we conduct a market
analysis will enable us to identify a
replacement for the competitive
showing rules that will allow us to more
effectively evaluate requests for pricing
flexibility. Thus, we disagree with
commenters who assert that precedent
requires a different result.
83. Data Collection Necessary. We do
not agree with commenters that it is
necessary to collect additional data
prior to suspending our rules. As
discussed in section 0, above, the
existing record contains sufficient
evidence to call the continued viability
of the collocation-based competitive
showing rules into question. We
therefore will not allow the
inefficiencies resulting from those rules
to go unaddressed until we are able to
obtain a more extensive data set. In our
view, it is appropriate to suspend the
competitive showing rules adopted in
the Pricing Flexibility Order while we
undertake a competition analysis to
assist us in determining how to assess
the presence of actual and potential
competition sufficient to discipline
special access prices.
D. Changes in Regulatory Relief During
Development of New Rules
84. We note that parties may still take
steps to alter the regulatory status of
special access services during the
pendency of this proceeding. As
commenters have noted, the
Commission has the power to resolve
allegations of unjust or unreasonable
rates, terms and conditions through the
complaint process in the Act, rather
than through a rulemaking proceeding.
Parties also may petition for forbearance
from any regulation or provision of the
Act pursuant to sec. 10 thereof, or seek
a waiver of our rules. The availability of
these forms of recourse provides
additional support for suspension of our
competitive showing rules pending
development of an improved method for
providing regulatory relief.
V. Undertaking a Market Analysis for
Special Access Regulatory Relief
A. Future Steps to Analyze Competition
for Special Access
85. In this section, we commence a
process that will enable us to more
effectively determine where regulatory
relief is appropriate. In the coming
months, we will undertake a robust
market analysis to assist us in
determining how best to assess the
presence of actual and potential
competition for special access that is
sufficient to discipline prices. Our
analysis will follow the collection of
additional data and an opportunity for
PO 00000
Frm 00040
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
public comment. As described below,
there is widespread accord in the record
on the appropriateness of collecting
additional data to inform our future
actions.
86. The market analysis we will
undertake in the coming months may
identify reliable proxies for competition
for special access services, which we
could adopt in lieu of the 1999
competitive showings. Our analysis may
also provide evidence that changes in
our regulatory approach are warranted
in particular geographic areas. At this
time, we do not exhaustively specify the
factors that will comprise our market
analysis: these will be subject to
comment by interested parties in an
upcoming notice. We anticipate that the
analysis will be a one-time assessment
of the competitive conditions in the
special access market; however, we do
not foreclose the possibility that further
analyses may be needed in the future. In
any event, we will issue a
comprehensive data collection order
within 60 days to facilitate this market
analysis.
B. Benefits of a More Complete Market
Analysis
1. A Market Analysis is Consistent With
Agency and Court Precedent
87. We concur with commenters who
point out that use of market analysis in
the special access context is consistent
with Commission precedent. The
Commission historically has conducted
an examination of market conditions in
several instances to assess competition
for telecommunications services. In a
series of orders in the Competitive
Carrier proceedings, the Commission
established a framework to evaluate
competition in telecommunications
markets and determine whether
deregulatory treatment of certain
carriers is warranted. In those orders,
the Commission performed a structural
market analysis to distinguish between
‘‘dominant carriers,’’ which ‘‘possess
market power (i.e., the power to control
price),’’ and ‘‘non-dominant carriers,’’
which ‘‘do not possess power over
price.’’ The Commission focused its
inquiry on certain ‘‘clearly identifiable
market features,’’ including a carrier’s
market share, number and size
distribution of competing firms, the
nature of competitors’ barriers to entry,
the availability of reasonably
substitutable services, the level of
demand elasticity, and whether the firm
controlled bottleneck facilities. This
analysis was designed to identify when
competition is sufficient to constrain
carriers from imposing unjust,
unreasonable, or unjustly or
E:\FR\FM\18SER1.SGM
18SER1
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES
Federal Register / Vol. 77, No. 181 / Tuesday, September 18, 2012 / Rules and Regulations
unreasonably discriminatory rates,
terms, and conditions, or from acting in
an anticompetitive manner. The
Commission subsequently applied the
same framework to reclassify AT&T as
non-dominant in the interstate
interexchange service market, finding
that AT&T no longer possessed
individual market power with respect to
those services.
88. In the 1997 LEC Classification
Order, the Commission modified its
framework for dominance/nondominance analyses to bring the
framework into accord with the antitrust
analysis laid out in the 1992 Merger
Guidelines, a precursor to the 2010
Horizontal Merger Guidelines that are in
use today. In that order, the Commission
stated that the assessment of
competitive conditions requires a
thorough analysis which begins with a
delineation of the relevant product and
geographic markets, and then considers
market characteristics, including market
shares, the potential for the exercise of
market power, and whether potential
entry would be timely, likely, and
sufficient to counteract the exercise of
market power.
89. More recently, the Commission
has undertaken market analysis to
assess the extent of competition in both
merger proceedings and in the
evaluation of forbearance petitions. For
instance, in its analysis of the proposed
AT&T/BellSouth and Verizon/MCI
mergers, the Commission considered
whether the mergers would reduce
existing competition, as well as their
likely effects on the market power of
dominant firms in the relevant
communications markets and the
mergers’ effects on future competition.
Similarly, in the Qwest Phoenix
Forbearance Order the Commission
employed a structural market analysis
akin to that of the Competitive Carrier
cases to evaluate Qwest’s petition for
forbearance from certain wholesale and
retail regulations in the Phoenix,
Arizona, MSA. Additionally, a market
analysis is consistent with the
investigation performed by the DOJ and
FTC to assess whether a horizontal
merger could adversely impact
competition in relevant markets.
90. In the Pricing Flexibility Order,
the Commission declined to require
incumbent LECs to perform a complete
market analysis as part of the carrier’s
application for pricing flexibility and
instead, without the benefit of a fulsome
market analysis, adopted proxies for
competition that were intended to
measure whether actual or potential
competition was sufficient to ensure just
and reasonable rates, terms and
conditions for special access services.
VerDate Mar<15>2010
16:24 Sep 17, 2012
Jkt 226001
As discussed above and based on the
record in this proceeding, we have
suspended grants of pricing flexibility
on the basis of these proxies because we
find that the geographic market over
which relief is granted, MSAs, do not
correspond to the scope of competitive
entry and serious question have been
raised concerning whether the presence
of collocation and competitive transport
are reliable indicators of the presence of
competitive channel termination
services. The process we begin today
may well assist in developing new
proxies for special access competition,
which could be employed going forward
to evaluate petitions for pricing
flexibility. Once we have had the
opportunity to collect and analyze
additional data, we will be better
positioned to determine what specific
showings price cap carriers must make
in their petitions for pricing flexibility
and what information they could submit
to satisfy those showings.
2. A Market Analysis Will Provide
Analytical Precision
91. Several commenters recommend
that, prior to adopting a new analytical
framework, we collect competitive data
to assess whether the current
competitive showing rules are a
reasonably accurate proxy for the
presence of competition. Undertaking a
market analysis will allow the
Commission to more precisely
determine where competition exists, or
could potentially exist, and to develop
better tests for regulatory relief to
replace the current collocation-based
approach. For example, as described
above, some commenters observe that
the collocation-based competitive
showings do not account for sources of
intermodal and/or intramodal
competition that do not collocate in
incumbent LEC facilities. Other
commenters raise concerns that the
1999 competitive showing rules
overlook competitors who could
potentially enter the market in the near
term or in the more distant future. In
contrast to our current approach, a
market analysis would seek to identify
significant current and potential market
participants, and consider their impact
when assessing the level of competition
in a market.
92. Several commenters state that a
single market characteristic (e.g., high
special access rates or carrier revenues,
large market share) is generally not
sufficient on its own to signify whether
a given market is competitive. For
example, AT&T and Verizon both assert
that the Commission should not rely on
market share as the basis for concluding
that a given market lacks competition,
PO 00000
Frm 00041
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
57521
because market share is a static measure
that can understate the impact of
competitive alternatives in dynamic
markets. We agree that the Commission
must conduct a more comprehensive
analysis of the state of competition prior
to adopting replacement competitive
proxies or making other changes to the
ways that incumbent LECs may obtain
regulatory relief in the provision of
special access services. A market
analysis will enable us to make a multifaceted assessment of competition that
considers a variety of factors, including
both price and non-price effects.
Additionally, this type of fact-specific
analysis is in line with current
approaches to competition policy.
3. A Market Analysis Will Foster
Broadband Deployment and
Competition
93. Finally, a comprehensive market
analysis will help us to take future steps
to support broadband deployment and
competition. In the Qwest Phoenix
Forbearance Order, the Commission
found that, ‘‘by using the more
comprehensive antitrust-based analysis
that the Commission frequently has
used in past proceedings, and that the
[FTC and DOJ] regularly use to measure
competition, we ensure that competition
in downstream markets is not negatively
affected by premature forbearance from
regulatory obligations in upstream
markets.’’ Citing the National
Broadband Plan, the Commission noted
that ‘‘regulatory policies for wholesale
access affect the competitiveness of
markets for retail broadband services
provided to small businesses, mobile
customers and enterprise customers.’’
94. Special access circuits are a
particularly important input for carriers’
broadband service offerings. As the
National Broadband Plan found, the
costs associated with purchasing special
access circuits can be a significant
expense that impacts a carrier’s ability
to provide affordable broadband service,
particularly to smaller, rural
communities.
95. A market analysis will enable us
to ensure that appropriate regulatory
relief is granted in those markets where
competitive conditions justify it. For
example, we expect that our analysis
will aid in determining whether
purchasers can obtain special access
circuits at just and reasonable prices.
This inquiry could provide insight into
challenges that carriers may face in
deploying broadband and what actions,
if any, are needed to respond to those
challenges.
E:\FR\FM\18SER1.SGM
18SER1
57522
Federal Register / Vol. 77, No. 181 / Tuesday, September 18, 2012 / Rules and Regulations
4. Factors to be Considered in Market
Analysis
96. Some commenters, in particular
incumbent LECs, recommend specific
factors or considerations they believe
the Commission should include in a
market analysis. We address several of
these recommendations below.
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES
a. Analysis Must Be Forward-Looking
and Consider Various Sources of
Competition
97. As detailed below, commenters
state that any market analysis we
conduct must be forward-looking and
account for significant competitors in a
market. We agree.
98. In our view, a comprehensive
market analysis will best facilitate a
complete inquiry into the existence of
competition in a given market,
including sources of intermodal and
intramodal competition, potential
market entrants, uncommitted entrants,
carriers that self-supply their own
special access, and non-facilities-based
competitors. This analysis also will
consider the impact of competitors that
do not collocate in an incumbent’s wire
center.
99. For instance, the 2010 Horizontal
Merger Guidelines contain a detailed
process employed to identify
participants in the relevant market.
Pursuant to the 2010 Horizontal Merger
Guidelines, an identification of market
participants includes all firms that
currently earn revenues in the relevant
market. A firm may be considered to be
a market participant even if it does not
currently earn revenues, but it is
‘‘committed to entering the market in
the near future,’’ or if the firm is not a
current producer in the relevant market,
but ‘‘would very likely provide rapid
supply responses with direct
competitive impact in the event of a
[small but significant and non-transitory
increase in price (SSNIP)], without
incurring significant sunk costs.’’ Thus,
in those instances where a competitor,
such as a cable or fixed wireless
provider, can quickly enter the market
and respond to customer demand, a
market analysis would enable us to
consider the likely impact of that entry
on competition.
100. Moreover, a market analysis
allows for specific, economically
rigorous, and factually specific inquiries
regarding potential competition, a factor
that price cap LECs such as Verizon and
AT&T contend should be included in
any framework we adopt. A market
analysis of potential competition
assesses whether a firm is perceived to
be a potential competitor, exerting a
price-constraining effect on firms
VerDate Mar<15>2010
16:24 Sep 17, 2012
Jkt 226001
currently participating in the market,
even though it is not currently
participating in the market. We agree
with commenters that our analysis of
competitive conditions should
incorporate an assessment of potential
competition. We also agree that barriers
to market entry should be considered.
Entry is an important consideration in a
structural analysis, as the exercise of
market power is unlikely where entry
barriers are low and incumbents cannot
profitably raise price or otherwise
reduce competition to a level below that
of a competitive market. In the past, the
Commission has considered potential
competition and barriers to entry as part
of its market analysis.
101. Further, we concur with
commenters that the multi-faceted and
forward-looking analysis of competition
we will undertake would be inadequate
if it focused solely on market share or
building counts. By examining factors
such as the potential for competitive
effects, market entry, and potential
competition, a market analysis is a
forward-looking alternative to the
current competitive showing rules or
any like standard. That being said, we
must carefully balance the benefits of
relying on solid, if historical data,
against the risks associated with placing
too much weight on speculative data
sources. We will continue to consider
our future data collection needs with
these points in mind.
b. Approach That Enhances Consumer
Welfare
102. We agree with commenters who
assert that the Commission must
conduct its market analysis in light of
its broader objectives for the
telecommunications industry. For
example, Verizon notes that pricing
flexibility was among several
deregulatory actions taken by the
Commission in the 1990s with the goal
of encouraging innovation, cost savings,
and efficiencies.
103. The major purpose of the 1996
Act was to establish ‘‘a pro-competitive,
deregulatory national policy
framework.’’ Indeed, among its primary
goals were ‘‘opening the local exchange
and exchange access markets to
competitive entry’’ and ‘‘promoting
increased competition in
telecommunications markets that are
already open to competition, including
the long-distance services market.’’ We
undertake an analytical process to
assess the level of competition in the
special access market with these goals
in mind. For example, our analysis may
indicate that further regulatory relief is
warranted in areas where competition
exists, but is not captured by the current
PO 00000
Frm 00042
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 4700
competitive proxies. As detailed above,
the competitive showings adopted in
the Pricing Flexibility Order are both
over- and under-inclusive, resulting in
inaccurate assessments of whether
actual and potential competition is
sufficient to constrain special access
prices in the areas granted relief.
Indeed, given the unreliable nature of
the competitive showing requirements
adopted in 1999, we believe a market
analysis will aid us in granting
deregulation in areas where actual and
potential competition is sufficient to
constrain prices. A nuanced market
analysis will also allow us to better
balance the potential costs of regulating
too heavily against the potential harms
of failing to undertake appropriate
regulation where it is needed.
c. Dominance/Non-Dominance
Classification
104. Finally, incumbent LECs assert
that special access pricing flexibility
should not be treated as akin to the nondominance analyses undertaken by the
Commission in the Competitive Carrier
proceeding. Further, AT&T argues that,
under a non-dominance framework,
upon a finding that an incumbent
lacked market power, the Commission
would have to reclassify the carrier as
non-dominant and relieve its dominant
carrier obligations. We agree with AT&T
that, once we have performed a broader
evaluation of competitive conditions,
our analysis may show that a carrier
classified as dominant does not possess
market power as defined in the
Competitive Carrier proceeding for a
particular special access service in a
geographic area. In that case, the
Commission may ultimately conclude
that it is appropriate to grant regulatory
relief in the form of non-dominance
treatment for the particular service and
geographic area. We will determine at a
future date what criteria the
Commission will consider to assess
whether a finding of non-dominance for
special access service is warranted in a
given area.
VI. Procedural Matters
A. Paperwork Reduction Act Analysis
105. This document does not contain
new or modified information collection
requirements subject to the Paperwork
Reduction Act of 1995 (PRA), Public
Law 104–13. In addition, therefore, it
does not contain any new or modified
information collection burden for small
business concerns with fewer than 25
employees, pursuant to the Small
Business Paperwork Relief Act of 2002,
Public Law 107–198, see 44 U.S.C.
3506(c)(4).
E:\FR\FM\18SER1.SGM
18SER1
Federal Register / Vol. 77, No. 181 / Tuesday, September 18, 2012 / Rules and Regulations
B. Final Regulatory Flexibility
Certification
106. As required by the Regulatory
Flexibility Act (RFA), an Initial
Regulatory Flexibility Analysis (IRFA)
was incorporated into the 2005 Special
Access NPRM. The Commission sought
written public comment on the possible
significant economic impact on small
entities regarding the proposals
addressed in the 2005 Special Access
NPRM, including comments on the
IRFA.
107. As required by sec. 603 of the
RFA, the Commission has prepared a
Final Regulatory Flexibility Certification
(FRFC) of the expected impact on small
entities of the requirements adopted in
the Report and Order, which is set forth
in Appendix B of the Report and Order.
The Commission will send a copy of the
Report and Order, including the FRFC,
to the Chief Counsel for Advocacy of the
Small Business Administration.
C. Congressional Review Act
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with RULES
108. The Commission will send a
copy of this Report and Order to
Congress and the Government
Accountability Office pursuant to the
Congressional Review Act.
VerDate Mar<15>2010
16:24 Sep 17, 2012
Jkt 226001
II. Ordering Clauses
109. Accordingly, it is ordered that
pursuant to sections 1, 4(i), 4(j), and
201–205 of the Communications Act of
1934, as amended, 47 U.S.C. 151, 154(i),
154(j), 201, 202, 203, 204, 205, this
Report and Order is adopted.
110. It is further ordered that part 1
of the Commission’s rules is amended as
set forth in the final rules, and such rule
amendments shall be effective October
18, 2012.
111. It is further ordered that
§ 1.774(f)(1) of the Commission’s rules,
47 CFR 1.774(f)(1), is suspended until
the amendments set forth in the final
rules are effective.
112. It is further ordered that,
pursuant to §§ 1.4(b)(1) and 1.103(a) of
the Commission’s rules, 47 CFR
1.4(b)(1), 1.103(a), this Report and Order
is effective upon release.
113. It is further ordered that the
Commission will send a copy of this
Report and Order to Congress and the
Government Accountability Office
pursuant to the Congressional Review
Act, see 5 U.S.C. 801(a)(1)(A).
114. It is further ordered that the
Commission’s Consumer and
Governmental Affairs Bureau, Reference
Information Center, shall send a copy of
this Report and Order, including the
PO 00000
Frm 00043
Fmt 4700
Sfmt 9990
57523
Final Regulatory Flexibility
Certification, to the Chief Counsel for
Advocacy of the Small Business
Administration.
List of Subjects in 47 CFR Part 1
Administrative practice and
procedure, Communications common
carriers, Telecommunications.
Federal Communications Commission
Marlene H. Dortch,
Secretary.
Final Rule
For the reasons discussed in the
preamble, the Federal Communications
Commission amends 47 CFR Part 1 as
follows:
PART 1—PRACTICE AND
PROCEDURE
1. The authority citation for part 1
continues to read as follows:
■
Authority: 15 U.S.C. 79, et seq., 47 U.S.C.
151, 154(i), 154(j), 155, 157, 225, 227, 303(r)
and 309.
§ 1.774
[Amended]
2. In § 1.774, remove and reserve
paragraph (f)(1).
■
[FR Doc. 2012–23020 Filed 9–17–12; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6712–01–P
E:\FR\FM\18SER1.SGM
18SER1
Agencies
[Federal Register Volume 77, Number 181 (Tuesday, September 18, 2012)]
[Rules and Regulations]
[Pages 57504-57523]
From the Federal Register Online via the Government Printing Office [www.gpo.gov]
[FR Doc No: 2012-23020]
=======================================================================
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION
47 CFR Part 1
[WC Docket No. 05-25; RM-10593; FCC 12-92]
Special Access for Price Cap Local Exchange Carriers; AT&T
Corporation Petition for Rulemaking To Reform Regulation of Incumbent
Local Exchange Carrier Rates for Interstate Special Access Services
AGENCY: Federal Communications Commission.
ACTION: Final rule.
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
SUMMARY: In this Report and Order, the Commission suspends, on an
interim basis, the Commission's rules allowing for automatic pricing
flexibility grants for special access services, pending adoption of new
rules. The Commission suspends its pricing flexibility rules in light
of evidence that the proxies for measuring actual and potential special
access market competition, which are based on collocation by
competitive carriers within a Metropolitan Statistical Area (MSA), do
not accurately predict whether competition is sufficient to constrain
special access prices and deter anticompetitive practices by price cap
local exchange carriers. In the Report and Order, the Commission also
initiates a process to obtain data needed to conduct a special access
market analysis. Based on this forthcoming data collection, the
Commission will undertake a robust special access market analysis to
determine the extent to which the special access market is competitive
and develop special access pricing flexibility rules to replace the
collocation-based competitive showings.
DATES: Effective October 18, 2012,
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: Jamie Susskind, Wireline Competition
Bureau, Pricing Policy Division, (202) 418-1520 or (202) 418-0484
(TTY), or via email at Jamie.Susskind@fcc.gov.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: This is a summary of the Commission's Report
and Order in WC Docket No. 05-25, RM-10593, FCC 12-92, adopted on
August 15, 2012 and released on August 22, 2012. The summary is based
on the public redacted version of the document, the full text of which
is available electronically via the Electronic Comment Filing System at
https://fjallfoss.fcc.gov/ecfs/ or may be downloaded at https://transition.fcc.gov/Daily_Releases/Daily_Business/2012/db0823/FCC-12-92A1.pdf. The full text of this document is also available for public
inspection during regular business hours in the Commission's Reference
Center, 445 12th Street SW., Room CY-A257, Washington, DC 20554. The
complete text may be purchased from Best Copy and Printing, Inc., 445
12th Street, SW., Room CY-B402, Washington, DC 20554. To request
alternate formats for persons with disabilities (e.g. Braille, large
print, electronic files, audio format, etc.) or reasonable
accommodations for filing comments (e.g. accessible format documents,
sign language interpreters, CARTS, etc.), send an email to
fcc504@fcc.gov or call the Commission's Consumer and Governmental
Affairs Bureau at (202) 418-0530 (voice) or (202) 418-0432 (TTY).
I. Introduction
1. In this Report and Order, we suspend, on an interim basis, our
rules
[[Page 57505]]
allowing for automatic grants of pricing flexibility for special access
services in light of significant evidence that these rules, adopted in
1999, are not working as predicted, and widespread agreement across
industry sectors that these rules fail to accurately reflect
competition in today's special access markets. We set forth a path to
update our rules to better target regulatory relief to competitive
areas, including extending relief to areas that are likely competitive
but have been denied regulatory relief under our existing framework. We
provide for targeted relief in the interim through the forbearance
process set forth in sec. 10 of the 1996 Act, and will soon issue a
comprehensive data collection order that will help craft permanent
replacement rules.
2. Special access continues to play a critical role in our economy.
Four of the largest incumbent LECs recently reported that their
combined 2010 revenues from sales of DS1s and DS3s exceeded $12
billion. Competitive carriers rely heavily on special access to reach
customers; a large competitive local exchange carrier (LEC) that offers
enterprise services to businesses using special access services as a
critical input has reported that it purchases [lsqbb]REDACTED[rsqbb]
times as many special access as Ethernet circuits. Enterprise customers
across the country rely on special access--directly or indirectly--to
conduct their business. Schools, libraries, and other institutions of
state and local government depend on special access to provide services
to their constituents.
3. We continue to strongly believe, consistent with the goals set
forth in the Pricing Flexibility Order, that regulation should be
reduced wherever evidence demonstrates that actual or potential
competition is acting as a constraint to ensure just and reasonable
rates, terms and conditions for special access services. In the record
of this proceeding, however, there is compelling evidence that our
current pricing flexibility rules are not properly matching relief to
such areas, combined with allegations that this mismatch is causing
real harm to American consumers and businesses and hindering investment
and innovation. Price cap carriers argue that they are still subject to
burdensome regulation in areas where it is apparent that competition is
thriving. The United States Small Business Administration asserts that
``promoting competition in the business broadband market is essential
in order to provide small businesses with affordable access and choice
regarding the services they need to grow and create new jobs.'' The
American Petroleum Institute expresses concern that, because its member
companies' facilities are frequently located in isolated locations
where facilities-based competition is scarce, they are highly sensitive
to incumbent LECs extracting supra-competitive profits. Competitive
carriers argue that the terms and conditions of special access contract
tariffs ``lock up'' demand, preventing competitors from entering
markets and investing in new facilities. Wireless providers argue that
high special access prices hinder their ability to hire employees,
invest in their networks, and conduct research and development. While
we cannot yet evaluate these claims of competitive harm based on the
evidence to date in the record, our finding that the competitive
showings the Commission adopted as a proxy for competition are not
working as predicted leads us to suspend the triggers and further
evaluate the marketplace.
4. The approach we take is based on our evaluation of our 1999
rules, the predictive judgments upon which they were based, and market
developments since their adoption. As discussed in greater detail
below, the Commission decided in 1999 to use an administratively simple
proxy for the presence of actual or potential competition in special
access markets--the extent of collocation within broad geographic
regions. The Commission predicted that certain levels of collocation
within a Metropolitan Statistical Area (MSA) would serve as an accurate
indicator of competitive pressure sufficient to constrain prices
throughout that area.
5. Based on the evidence in the record and thirteen years of
experience with this regime, we now conclude that the Commission's
existing collocation triggers are a poor proxy for the presence of
competition sufficient to constrain special access prices or deter
anticompetitive practices throughout an MSA. We therefore suspend, on
an interim basis, the operation of those rules pending adoption of a
new framework that will allow us to ensure that special access prices
are fair and competitive in all areas of the country.
6. Although we currently lack the necessary data to identify a
permanent reliable replacement approach to measure the presence of
competition for special access services, we emphasize that the
forbearance process set forth by Congress in the 1996 Act provides an
avenue for targeted relief based on a complete analysis of competitive
conditions in a geographic area.
7. Going forward, in the absence at this time of clear evidence to
establish reasonable and reliable proxies to determine where regulatory
relief is appropriate, we will collect necessary data and undertake a
robust competition analysis that may identify reliable proxies for
competition in the market for special access services going forward. We
will issue a comprehensive data collection order within 60 days to
facilitate this market analysis. We anticipate that during the pendency
of the data request, we will continue to analyze the information
submitted in the record, and may issue further decisions as warranted
by the evidence. Nonetheless, the record in this proceeding
demonstrates that a comprehensive evaluation of competition in the
market for special access services is necessary, and that further data
to assist us in that evaluation is needed with respect to establishing
a new framework for pricing flexibility.
II. Background
A. History of Price Cap Regulation
8. Through the end of 1990, interstate access charges were governed
by ``rate-of-return'' regulation, under which incumbent LECs calculated
their access rates using projected costs and projected demand for
access services. An incumbent LEC was limited to recovering its costs
plus a prescribed return on investment. It also was potentially
obligated to provide refunds if its interstate rate of return exceeded
the authorized level. However, a rate of return regulatory structure
bases a firm's allowable rates directly on the firm's reported costs
and was thus subject to criticisms that it removed the incentive to
reduce costs and improve productive efficiency.
9. Consequently, in 1991 the Commission implemented a system of
price cap regulation that altered the manner in which the largest
incumbent LECs (often referred to today as price cap LECs) established
their interstate access charges. The Commission's price cap plan for
LECs was intended to avoid the perverse incentives of rate-of-return
regulation in part by divorcing the annual rate adjustments from the
cost performance of each individual LEC, and provide for sharing
efficiency gains with customers in part by adjusting the cap based on
industry productivity experience.
10. In contrast to rate-of-return regulation, which focuses on an
incumbent LEC's costs and fixes the profits an incumbent LEC may earn
based on those costs, price cap regulation focuses primarily on the
prices that an incumbent LEC may
[[Page 57506]]
charge. The access charges of price cap LECs originally were set at
levels based on the rates that existed at the time the LECs entered the
price cap regime. Increases in their rates have, however, been limited
over the course of price cap regulation by price indices that are
adjusted annually pursuant to formulae set forth in Part 61 of our
rules. Price cap regulation is a form of incentive regulation that
seeks to ``harness the profit-making incentives common to all
businesses to produce a set of outcomes that advance the public
interest goals of just, reasonable, and nondiscriminatory rates, as
well as a communications system that offers innovative, high quality
services.'' A core component of our price cap regulation is the Price
Cap Index (PCI). As the Commission has explained previously, the PCI is
designed to limit the prices LECs charge for service. The PCI provides
a benchmark of LEC cost changes that encourages price cap LECs to
become more productive and innovative by permitting them to retain
reasonably higher earnings. The PCI has three basic components: (1) A
measure of inflation, i.e., the Gross Domestic Product (chain weighted)
Price Index (GDP-PI); (2) a productivity factor or ``X-Factor,'' that
represents the amount by which LECs can be expected to outperform
economy-wide productivity gains; and (3) adjustments to account for
``exogenous'' cost changes that are outside the LEC's control and not
otherwise reflected in the PCI.
B. Pricing Flexibility
11. Pursuant to the pro-competitive, deregulatory mandates of the
1996 Act, the Commission in 1996 began exploring whether and how to
remove price cap LECs' access services from price cap and tariff
regulation once they are subject to substantial competition. Three
years later, in 1999, the Commission adopted the Pricing Flexibility
Order in an effort to ensure that the Commission's interstate access
charge regulations did not unduly interfere with the operation of
interstate access markets as competition developed in those markets.
The Commission developed competitive showings (also referred to as
``triggers'') designed to measure the extent to which competitors had
made irreversible, sunk investment in collocation and transport
facilities. Price cap carriers that demonstrated the competitive
showings were met in their serving areas could obtain so-called
``pricing flexibility,'' namely the ability to offer special access
services at unregulated rates through generally available and
individually negotiated tariffs (i.e., contract tariffs). The operation
of the pricing flexibility rules is discussed in greater detail in
section 0 below.
C. The CALLS Order
12. In 2000, after a comprehensive examination of the interstate
access charge and universal service regulatory regimes for price cap
carriers, the Commission adopted the industry-proposed CALLS plan. This
plan represented a five-year interim regime designed to phase down
implicit subsidies and (as it pertained to switched and special access
charges) to move towards a more market-based approach to rate setting.
In adopting the CALLS plan, the Commission offered price cap carriers
the choice of completing the forward-looking cost studies required by
the Access Charge Reform Order or voluntarily making the rate
reductions required under the five-year CALLS plan. The Commission
permitted carriers to defer the planned forward-looking cost studies in
favor of the CALLS plan because it found the plan to be ``a
transitional plan that move[d] the marketplace closer to economically
rational competition, and it [would] enable [the Commission], once such
competition develops, to adjust our rules in light of relevant
marketplace developments.'' All price cap carriers opted for the CALLS
plan.
13. The CALLS plan separated special access services into their own
basket and applied a separate X-factor to the special access basket.
The X-factor under the CALLS plan, unlike under prior price cap
regimes, is not a productivity factor. Rather, it represents ``a
transitional mechanism * * * to lower rates for a specified period of
time for special access.'' The special access X-factor was 3.0 percent
in 2000 and 6.5 percent in 2001, 2002, and 2003. In addition to the X-
factor, access charges under CALLS are adjusted for inflation as
measured by the GDP-PI. For the final year of the CALLS plan (July 1,
2004-June 30, 2005), the special access X-factor was set equal to
inflation, thereby freezing rate levels. Thus, in the absence of a new
price cap regime post-CALLS, price cap LECs' special access rates have
remained frozen at 2003 levels (excluding any necessary exogenous cost
adjustments). The Commission hoped that, by the end of the five-year
CALLS plan, competition would exist to such a degree that deregulation
of access charges (switched and special) for price cap LECs would be
the next logical step.
D. AT&T's Petition for Rulemaking and 2005 Special Access NPRM
14. On October 15, 2002, AT&T Corp. filed a petition for rulemaking
requesting that the Commission revoke the pricing flexibility rules and
revisit the CALLS plan as it pertains to the rates that price cap LECs,
and the BOCs in particular, charge for special access services. AT&T
claimed that the competitive showings required to obtain pricing
flexibility failed to predict price-constraining competitive entry and,
rather, that significant competitive entry had not occurred. It further
contended that, based on Automated Reporting Management Information
System (ARMIS) data, the BOCs' interstate special access revenues had
more than tripled, from $3.4 billion to $12.0 billion, between 1996 and
2001 and that the BOCs' returns on special access services were between
21 and 49 percent in 2001. Further, AT&T stated that, in every MSA for
which pricing flexibility was granted, BOC special access rates either
remained flat or increased. Thus, AT&T contended both that the
predictive judgment at the core of the Pricing Flexibility Order had
not been confirmed by marketplace developments, and that BOC special
access rates exceeded competitive levels and hence were unjust and
unreasonable in violation of Sec. 201 of the Communications Act.
Because the predictive judgment had proven wrong, AT&T asserted, the
Commission was compelled to revisit its pricing flexibility rules in a
rulemaking proceeding.
15. Price cap LECs generally opposed the AT&T Petition for
Rulemaking. They claimed that their special access rates were
reasonable and therefore lawful, that there was robust competition for
special access services, that the collocation-based competitive
showings were an accurate metric for competition, and that the data
relied upon by AT&T were unreliable in the context used by AT&T. SBC
noted that AT&T only provided (and could only provide) data from a
single year (2001) that post-dated the initial implementation of Phase
II pricing flexibility in 2001, and SBC and Verizon claimed that ARMIS
data were not designed to evaluate the reasonableness of rates. The
BOCs contended, moreover, that special access revenues per line
declined between 1996 and 2001.
16. On January 31, 2005, the Commission released the Special Access
NPRM. The Special Access NPRM initiated a broad examination of what
regulatory framework to apply to price cap LECs' interstate special
access
[[Page 57507]]
services following the expiration of the CALLS plan, including whether
to maintain or modify the Commission's pricing flexibility rules for
special access services. As part of our review of the pricing
flexibility rules, which were adopted, in part, based on the
Commission's predictive judgment, the Commission sought to examine
whether the available marketplace data supported maintaining,
modifying, or repealing these rules. The Commission noted its
commitment to re-examine periodically rules that were adopted on the
basis of predictive judgments to evaluate whether those judgments are,
in fact, corroborated by marketplace developments. Accordingly, the
Commission sought data and comments on whether actual marketplace
developments supported the predictive judgments used to support the
special access pricing flexibility rules.
17. The Special Access NPRM also responded to AT&T's request for
interim relief. AT&T asked, in addition to initiating a rulemaking,
that the Commission reinitialize Phase II pricing flexibility special
access rates at an 11.25 percent rate of return, and impose a temporary
moratorium on further pricing flexibility applications. These requests
were denied; however, the Commission sought comment on whether to adopt
any interim requirements in the event that the Commission was unable to
conclude the NPRM in time for any adopted rule changes to be
implemented in the 2005 annual tariff filings.
E. Recent Actions in the Proceeding
1. Refresh Record
18. In July 2007, the Commission invited interested parties to
update the record in the special access rulemaking in light of a number
of recent developments in the industry, including several ``significant
mergers and other industry consolidation,'' ``the continued expansion
of intermodal competition in the market for telecommunications
services,'' and ``the release by GAO [the Government Accountability
Office] of a report summarizing its review of certain aspects of the
market for special access services.'' While the special access
rulemaking was pending, the Commission also addressed special access
regulation for price cap carriers in several other proceedings. A
petition for forbearance from dominant carrier regulation of enterprise
broadband special access services (i.e., packet-based switched, high-
speed telecommunications services for businesses) filed by Verizon was
deemed granted in 2006. In orders issued in October 2007 and August
2008, the agency granted petitions filed by AT&T, Embarq, Frontier, and
Qwest under 47 U.S.C. Sec. 160 seeking similar forbearance relief,
and, in August 2008, granted Qwest's petition for similar relief from
regulation of enterprise broadband special access.
2. Analytical Framework
19. In November 2009, the Commission sought comment on the
appropriate analytical framework for examining the issues that the
Special Access NPRM raised. In July 2010, the Commission's Wireline
Competition Bureau (Bureau) held a staff workshop on the economics of
special access to gather further input from interested parties on the
analytical framework the Commission should use--and the data it should
collect--to evaluate whether the current special access rules are
working as intended.
3. Voluntary Data Requests
20. In October 2010, the Bureau issued a public notice inviting the
public to submit data on the presence of competitive special access
facilities to assist the Commission in evaluating the issues that the
Special Access NPRM raised. Explaining that data ``would need to be
reviewed'' before the Commission could address the issues raised by the
proceeding, the Bureau asked that the requested data be submitted by
January 27, 2011. The Bureau also noted that while it continued to
develop an analytical framework, it would ``ask for additional
voluntary submissions of data in a second public notice.''
21. On September 19, 2011, the Bureau issued a second public notice
requesting the submission of special access data. In this request, the
Bureau sought detailed data on special access prices, revenues, and
expenditures, as well as the nature of terms and conditions for special
access services. The Bureau requested that the data be submitted to the
Commission by December 5, 2011.
III. The ``Competitive Showings'' Adopted in 1999 Have Not Worked as
Expected
22. In the Pricing Flexibility Order, the Commission adopted rules
intended to allow price cap LECs to show, in an administratively
workable way, that certain parts of the country were sufficiently
competitive to warrant pricing flexibility for special access services.
As discussed in greater detail below, we find that the record indicates
that the administratively simple competitive showings we adopted in
1999 have not worked as intended, likely resulting in both over- and
under- regulation of special access in parts of the country. We
therefore suspend the pricing flexibility competitive showings, on an
interim basis, until we obtain the requisite data and conduct the
market analysis required to craft replacement rules.
A. Background
1. Rationale for Competitive Showings
23. In the Pricing Flexibility Order, the Commission adopted rules
that allow price cap LECs to obtain relief from pricing regulations as
competition for special access services increased. The Commission
concluded that relief should be granted in two phases. Phase I relief
permits price cap LECs the ability to lower their rates through
contract tariffs and volume and term discounts, but requires that they
maintain their generally available price cap-constrained tariff rates
to ``protect those customers that lack competitive alternatives.''
Phase II relief permits price cap LECs to raise or lower their rates
throughout an area, unconstrained by the Commission's part 61 and part
69 rules.
24. The Commission found that different levels of collocation in an
area would justify different levels of relief. Specifically, the
Commission held that Phase I deregulatory relief would be appropriate
in areas where the price cap LEC was able to show that competitors had
made irreversible, sunk investment sufficient to ``discourage[e]
incumbent LECs from successfully pursuing exclusionary strategies,''
such as `` `locking up' large customers by offering them volume and
term discounts.''
25. The Commission held that Phase II deregulatory relief would be
appropriate only in areas where a price cap LEC could show there was a
higher level of collocation--specifically, that ``competitors have
established a significant market presence, i.e., that competition for a
particular service within the [area] is sufficient to preclude the
incumbent from exploiting any monopoly power over a sustained period.''
That is, competitors would have ``sufficient market presence to
constrain prices throughout the'' area because ``almost all special
access customers have a competitive alternative'' and ``[i]f an
incumbent LEC charges an unreasonably high rate for access to an area
that lacks a competitive alternative, that rate will induce competitive
entry, and that entry will in turn drive rates down.''
[[Page 57508]]
2. How the Competitive Showings Work
26. Geographic Area of Relief. The Commission chose to grant
pricing flexibility relief on an MSA basis, finding that, among the
proposed alternatives ``MSAs best reflect the scope of competitive
entry, and therefore are a logical basis for measuring the extent of
competition'' and avoiding the ``increased expenses and administrative
burdens associated with'' proposals to grant relief in smaller
geographic areas, such as wire centers. The Office of Management and
Budget (OMB) defines MSAs as geographic entities that contain a core
urban area of 50,000 or more population, and often includes adjacent
counties that have a high degree of social and economic integration
with the urban core, as measured by commuting to work. MSAs were
developed not for the purposes of competition policy, but to meet the
Federal Government's need to have ``nationally consistent definitions
for collecting, tabulating and publishing Federal statistics for a set
of geographic areas.'' OMB may add counties or principal cities to an
MSA, remove them, or even create new MSAs if census and population
estimates indicate changes in social and economic integration between
outlying areas and the urban core.
27. In the Pricing Flexibility Order, the Commission adopted a list
of 306 MSAs based largely on data compiled from the 1980 census, and
froze that list for use in all pricing flexibility petitions.
Therefore, even if OMB subsequently expanded the geographic area of an
MSA, a price cap LEC's grant of pricing flexibility remains within the
borders of the applied-for MSA. The Commission also recognized that
some price cap LEC study areas fall outside of MSA boundaries, and held
that it would ``grant price cap LECs pricing flexibility within the
non-MSA parts of a study area if'' they were able to make the required
showings ``throughout that area.''
28. MSAs can be geographically extensive and, in many cases, may
encompass areas with vastly different business density within their
borders. Some illustrative examples include the Pensacola, Florida MSA
and the Atlanta, Georgia MSA.
29. Proxies for Competitive Showings. For the sake of
administrative convenience, the Commission adopted proxies for
competition designed to allow price cap LECs to make the required
showings, ``with a minimum of administrative burden for the industry
and the Commission.'' Specifically, the Commission chose to ``rely on
collocation as a proxy for irreversible, sunk investment'' in special
access facilities and services. Collocation--as used in the competitive
showing rules--is an offering by an incumbent LEC whereby a requesting
telecommunications carrier's transmission equipment is located, for a
tariffed charge, at the incumbent LEC's central office. The Commission
predicted that collocation by competitors in incumbent LEC wire centers
would be a reliable indicator of competition because collocation
typically represented a financial investment by a competitor to
establish facilities within a wire center. The Commission predicted
that the collocation-based competitive showings would ``provide a
bright-line rule to guide the industry'' and ``an administratively
simple and readily verifiable mechanism for determining whether
competitive conditions warrant the grant of pricing flexibility.''
30. The Commission established bright line ``triggers'' based on
the extent of collocation within an MSA that it expected would allow a
price cap LEC to demonstrate that market conditions in a given MSA
would warrant relief. Specifically, the Commission held that price cap
LECs would need to demonstrate
either that (1) competitors unaffiliated with the incumbent LEC
have established operational collocation arrangements in a certain
percentage of the incumbent LEC's wire centers in an MSA, or (2)
unaffiliated competitors have established operational collocation
arrangements in wire centers accounting for a certain percentage of
the incumbent LEC's revenues from the services in question in that
MSA. In both cases, the incumbent also must show, with respect to
each wire center, that at least one collocator is relying on
transport facilities provided by a transport provider other than the
incumbent LEC.
The specific level of collocation required varies depending on whether
a price cap LEC is seeking Phase I or Phase II relief and whether it is
seeking relief for channel terminations or other special access
services.
31. On February 2, 2001, the U.S. Court of Appeals for the DC
Circuit upheld the Pricing Flexibility Order, finding that the
Commission made a reasonable policy determination and sufficiently
explained its basis for adopting the competitive showing requirements.
B. Subsequent Evidence Undermines the Commission's Previous Decision To
Measure Competitive Showings and Grant Relief on an MSA-Wide Basis and
Justifies Suspension of Rules
1. Original Rationale for Granting Pricing Flexibility in MSAs and Non-
MSA Portions of Study Areas
32. The Commission's 1999 Pricing Flexibility Order chose MSAs as
the basis for competitive analysis because the record at the time
indicated ``that MSAs best reflect the scope of competitive entry, and
therefore are a logical basis for measuring the extent of
competition.'' The Commission rejected larger geographic areas such as
states and LATAs ``[b]ecause competitive LECs generally do not enter
new markets on a statewide basis.'' Accordingly, ``granting pricing
flexibility over such a large geographic area would increase the
likelihood of exclusionary behavior by incumbent LECs, by granting them
flexibility in areas where competitors have not yet made irreversible
investment in facilities.''
33. The Commission rejected concerns from some parties that
``competition may exist in only a small part of an MSA,'' finding that
``[t]he triggers we establish * * * are sufficient to ensure that
competitors have made sufficient sunk investment within an MSA.'' The
Commission therefore rejected smaller geographies, such as wire
centers, concluding that ``the record does not suggest that this level
of detail justifies the increased expenses and administrative burdens
associated with these proposals.''
34. The Commission received little guidance from commenters on how
to establish an appropriate geographic area for grants of pricing
flexibility in areas that fall outside of MSAs. In the absence of such
guidance, the Commission allowed price cap LECs to make a competitive
showing for the entirety of the non-MSA portions of a study area for
which they sought relief. It decided against requiring competitive
showings at a more granular level--such as on a rural service area
(RSA) basis, stating that
* * * we expect competitors to enter MSA markets first and then
to extend their networks into less densely populated areas. Because
rural areas by definition do not have large concentrations of
population comparable to urban areas, we expect that competitive
entry into rural areas will be less concentrated than in urban
areas. Therefore, we do not expect that pricing flexibility will
enable an incumbent to engage successfully in exclusionary pricing
behavior with respect to one RSA because competitive entry is
limited to another RSA.
[[Page 57509]]
The Commission therefore placed more weight on administrative ease, and
chose to allow price cap LECs to apply for pricing flexibility for the
entirety of the non-MSA components of a study area.
2. The Record Now Suggests That Entry Occurs in Smaller Areas
35. The record in this proceeding suggests that, contrary to the
Commission's prediction in 1999, MSAs have generally failed to reflect
the scope of competitive entry. Rather, in many instances, the scope of
competitive entry has apparently been far smaller than predicted.
36. In the sections that follow, we evaluate whether record
evidence supports the Commission's prediction that MSAs and non-MSA
sections of incumbent LEC study areas best reflect the scope of
competitive entry. Entry is one of the many elements the Commission and
antitrust agencies analyze when evaluating competition. As a general
principle, firms are likely to enter a geographic area to compete ``if
the entrant generates sufficient revenue to cover all costs apart from
the sunk costs of entry. Such entry succeeds in the sense that the
entrant becomes and remains a viable competitor in the market.'' In
order to gauge whether entry would be profitable, firms are more likely
to focus on areas with high demand for their services, relative to the
cost of providing those services. Our review of the evidence suggests
that demand varies significantly within any MSA, with highly
concentrated demand in areas far smaller than the MSA. This leads us to
conclude that competitive entry is considerably less likely to be
profitable and hence is unlikely to occur in areas of low demand
throughout an MSA, regardless of whether the MSA also contains areas
with demand at sufficient levels to warrant competitive entry. This
conclusion is confirmed by the available data, including the record of
pricing flexibility grants since the Commission's 1999 Order, and data
on subsequent competitive developments in these areas.
a. Business Demand Varies Significantly Within MSAs
37. The Commission sought to define the geographic areas for which
pricing flexibility requests would be considered ``narrowly enough so
that the competitive conditions within each area are reasonably
similar, yet broadly enough to be administratively workable.'' Our
analysis of business establishment density indicates that business
demand can vary significantly across an MSA. This suggests that
competitive conditions within an MSA are also likely to vary
significantly, since areas with higher demand tend to be more capable
of supporting competition and are more attractive to potential entrants
than low demand areas. These data provide context for our analysis of
evidence about grants of pricing flexibility petitions and how
competitive entry has occurred since adoption of the Pricing
Flexibility Order.
38. The plots in Figures 1 and 2 below illustrate that business
demand varies significantly within MSAs. They show the distribution of
business establishment density by ZIP code in 12 of the sample of 24
MSAs for which we sought data in our voluntary data requests. Figure 1
shows the six MSAs with the least variance in business establishment
density across ZIP codes--Fayetteville, North Carolina; Johnstown,
Pennsylvania; Phoenix, Arizona; Ocala, Florida; Greenville-Spartanburg,
South Carolina; and Lima, Ohio. The distributions show that, even
within these relatively homogeneous MSAs, dense pockets of business
establishments exist, as well as areas in which business establishments
are few and far between. Johnstown, Pennsylvania is an extremely
concentrated example. In Johnstown, seventy-five percent of the ZIP
codes (from the minimum observation, represented by an upside-down
``T'' shape, to the top of the box) are clustered near the bottom of
the scale with densities close to zero, while the remaining twenty-five
percent (from the top of the box to the maximum observation,
represented by a ``T'' shape) are scattered along the vertical axis
between about five establishments per square mile and 230
establishments per square mile. The most dense ZIP code (15901), which
covers the central business district of Johnstown, is 23 times more
dense than the average zip code in the area. Phoenix is much larger and
somewhat more uniform than Johnstown, but is nonetheless characterized
by a few very dense ZIP codes amid a majority of less dense ZIP codes:
while the Phoenix MSA has three ZIP codes with over 300 establishments
per square mile, over half of the ZIP codes in the MSA have fewer than
40 establishments per square mile. Overall, these MSAs are similar in
that a small number of ZIP codes are far more dense than the rest.
39. The distributions shown in Figure 2 demonstrate more extreme
examples of intra-MSA variance of competitive conditions. Figure 2
depicts business establishment density variation for the six MSAs with
the most business establishment density variation across ZIP codes:
Chicago, Illinois; New Orleans, Louisiana; New York, New York; Seattle-
Everett, Washington; Washington, DC; and Los Angeles, California.
Except for New York, half of the ZIP codes in each MSA contain fewer
than 100 establishments per square mile, whereas other areas within
each MSA have upwards of 1,000 establishments per square mile.
BILLING CODE 6712-01-P
[[Page 57510]]
[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TR18SE12.070
[[Page 57511]]
[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TR18SE12.071
Billing Code 6712-01-C
40. This variance of competitive conditions within an MSA is an
artifact of the way MSAs are defined. The resulting statistical entity
can be large, including the entirety of distant counties if those
counties contain exurban areas linked to the core by commuting
behavior. The Atlanta, Georgia MSA, for example, includes Butts County,
Georgia (see Figure 3 below). Of the three ZIP codes within that
county, the densest (Jackson, Georgia 30233) has on average about 2.3
business establishments per square mile. This contrasts to the density
level of the central business district of Atlanta's MSA, which contains
thousands of business establishments per square mile. This kind of
variation is common across the 12 MSAs we have examined for these
purposes.
[[Page 57512]]
[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TR18SE12.072
41. Given the foregoing evidence that MSAs do not have ``reasonably
similar'' competitive conditions across their geographic areas, and as
discussed fully below, when such competitive conditions are considered
together with the evidence of how relief has been granted and how some
competitive entry has occurred, we can no longer conclude that MSAs
``best reflect the scope of competitive entry'' by LECs.
b. Prior Grants of Relief Suggest That Competitive LEC Entry Occurred
at a Smaller Geographic Level Than the MSA
42. Though the Commission acknowledged that demand for special
access services might be concentrated in certain areas, it designed the
competitive showings with the intent of ensuring that price cap LECs
could not obtain pricing flexibility throughout an MSA in instances of
extremely concentrated demand. While recognizing that ``a few wire
centers may account for a disproportionate share of revenues for a
particular service,'' the Commission attempted to set its revenue based
collocation triggers at levels designed to ``ensure that competitors
have extended their networks beyond a few revenue-intensive wire
centers.'' Our analysis indicates that the 1999 rules have not
effectively fulfilled this intent. This provides further evidence that
MSAs likely do not reflect the actual scope of competitive entry.
43. As noted above, the Commission adopted two types of rules by
which price cap LECs could make the competitive showings required to
obtain relief. The first type of rule permitted price cap LECs to
obtain relief by showing the presence of collocators in a certain
percentage of its wire centers within an MSA. The second type, the
revenue-based rule described above, reflected the Commission's
concession that demand for special access services is often
concentrated. Despite this concession, however, the Commission
cautioned that the revenue-based threshold for dedicated transport
services would need to be set high enough ``to ensure that competitors
have extended their networks beyond a few revenue-intensive wire
centers.'' With respect to channel terminations to end users, which the
Commission noted were less competitive than dedicated transport, it
doubled the revenue requirement for limited pricing flexibility and
increased by almost a third the requirement for full relief. In short,
the Commission made the revenue-based rule more difficult to meet
specifically to protect against grants of pricing flexibility based on
extremely concentrated demand.
44. We have analyzed the 217 incumbent LEC areas for which pricing
flexibility relief for channel terminations to end users was granted by
order of the Bureau, representing all such grants associated with
pricing flexibility petitions available in the Commission's Electronic
Tariff Filing System. These grants cover 199 MSAs and five non-MSAs.
The majority of those grants were based exclusively on the revenue-
based rule. Because the revenue-based rule has different revenue
thresholds for each type of special access service, the Commission
restricted its analysis to one type,
[[Page 57513]]
channel terminations to end users, to keep the analysis consistent.
45. This analysis shows that our rules permitted MSA-wide relief on
the basis of extremely concentrated demand in many instances. For
example, as detailed in the chart below, 72 of the 212 grants for MSAs
were based on revenues of no more than a quarter of the relevant wire
centers within the MSA. For example, AT&T obtained Phase II pricing
flexibility in the Pensacola MSA based on the revenues of three out of
12 wire centers. Further, 30 of those 72 grants were based on the
revenues of only one wire center, 12 were based on the revenues of only
two, and 5 were based on the revenues of only three.
Table 4--MSA-Wide Grants Based on Extremely Concentrated Demand
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Carrier name Competitive Showing
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Percent of
MSA At time of WCs with wire centers
Current grant collocation Total WCs with
collocation
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Alexandria, LA............... AT&T............ Bell South..... 1 10 10
Anderson, IN................. AT&T............ Ameritech...... 1 5 20
Anderson, SC................. AT&T............ Bell South..... 1 5 20
Asheville, NC................ AT&T............ Bell South..... 1 9 11
Bangor, ME................... Fairpoint....... Verizon........ 1 14 7
Burlington, NC............... AT&T............ Bell South..... 1 5 20
Columbus, GA-AL.............. AT&T............ Bell South..... 1 7 14
Evansville, IN-KY............ AT&T............ Bell South..... 1 4 25
Evansville-Henderson, IN-KY.. AT&T............ Ameritech...... 1 13 8
Gainesville, FL.............. AT&T............ Bell South..... 1 6 17
Harrisburg, PA............... CenturyLink..... Sprint......... 1 14 7
Jackson, MI.................. AT&T............ Ameritech...... 1 6 17
Joplin, MO................... AT&T............ SWBT........... 1 6 17
Kalamazoo, MI................ AT&T............ Ameritech...... 1 8 13
Lawton, OK................... AT&T............ SWBT........... 1 4 25
Lima, OH..................... CenturyLink..... Embarq......... 1 16 6
Medford, OR.................. CenturyLink..... Qwest.......... 1 7 14
Memphis, TN-AR-MS............ AT&T............ SWBT........... 1 5 20
Muncie, IN................... AT&T............ Ameritech...... 1 5 20
Ocala, FL.................... CenturyLink..... Sprint......... 1 10 10
Owensboro, KY................ AT&T............ Bell South..... 1 9 11
Panama City, FL.............. AT&T............ Bell South..... 1 5 20
Pittsburgh, PA............... CenturyLink..... Sprint......... 1 14 7
Pueblo, CO................... CenturyLink..... Qwest.......... 1 5 20
Salem, OR.................... CenturyLink..... Qwest.......... 1 7 14
Sioux City, IA-NE............ CenturyLink..... Qwest.......... 1 8 13
St. Cloud, MN................ CenturyLink..... Qwest.......... 1 8 13
St. Joseph, MO............... AT&T............ SWBT........... 1 5 20
Waco, TX..................... AT&T............ SWBT........... 1 14 7
Waterloo-Cedar Falls, IA..... CenturyLink..... Qwest.......... 1 6 17
Battle Creek, MI............. AT&T............ Ameritech...... 2 8 25
Boise City, ID............... CenturyLink..... Qwest.......... 2 8 25
Clarksville-Hopkinsville, TN/ AT&T............ Bell South..... 2 12 17
KY.
Eugene-Springfield, OR....... CenturyLink..... Qwest.......... 2 13 15
Fargo-Moorehead, ND-MN....... CenturyLink..... Qwest.......... 2 8 25
Fort Smith, AR-OK............ AT&T............ SWBT........... 2 11 18
Manchester, NH............... Frontier........ Verizon........ 2 13 15
Oxnard-Simi Valley-Ventura, AT&T............ Pac Bell....... 2 9 22
CA.
Provo-Orem, UT............... CenturyLink..... Qwest.......... 2 10 20
Springfield, IL.............. AT&T............ Ameritech...... 2 11 18
Springfield, MO.............. AT&T............ SWBT........... 2 12 17
Wilmington, NC............... AT&T............ Bell South..... 2 8 25
Augusta, GA.................. AT&T............ Bell South..... 3 13 23
Bloomington-Normal, IL....... Frontier........ Verizon........ 3 20 15
Chattanooga, TN-GA........... AT&T............ Bell South..... 3 13 23
Pensacola, FL................ AT&T............ Bell South..... 3 12 25
Portland, ME................. Fairpoint....... Verizon........ 3 22 14
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
46. In sum, more than a third of the cases in which pricing
flexibility was granted were premised on the existence of collocations
where 65 percent or more of the special access revenue generated within
the MSA came from 25 percent or fewer of the wire centers in the MSA.
This is consistent with extreme variations in business density.
Qualitatively, this suggests that MSA-wide grants of pricing
flexibility have encompassed areas in which little or no competitive
entry would be expected.
47. Even with more relaxed standards for what constitutes extremely
concentrated demand, the data shows that 97 grants were based on
revenues from less than a third of the wire centers, and 144 were based
on revenues from less than half of the wire centers. Conversely, only
28 grants were based on revenues of two-thirds or more of the wire
centers within the applied-for MSA.
[[Page 57514]]
c. Data Indicates That Competitive LEC Entry Occurs Only in Areas of
High Business Demand
48. Whereas our bright-line competitive showings suggested that
some MSAs would soon be, or already were, competitive more than a
decade ago, recent data indicates that competitors have a strong
tendency to enter in concentrated areas of high business demand, and
have not expanded beyond those areas despite the passage of more than a
decade since the grant of Phase II relief. This provides further
evidence that an MSA is probably a much larger area than a competitor
would typically choose to enter.
49. For example, data about the Atlanta MSA, where BellSouth was
granted Phase II relief in 2000, demonstrates the importance of
geographic business establishment density as a driver of competitive
entry. In 2011, staff collected data, on a voluntary basis, about the
presence of competitive special access facilities for channel
terminations to end users in 24 MSAs. The following providers submitted
data indicating that they provide facilities-based competition in parts
of the Atlanta MSA: [lsqbb]REDACTED[rsqbb]. The first of these carriers
is [lsqbb]REDACTED[rsqbb], another is the [lsqbb]REDACTED[rsqbb], and
three are among the nation's [lsqbb]REDACTED[rsqbb]. According to those
data, only 40 percent of the ZIP codes in the Atlanta MSA had
competitive access facilities supplied by even one of the
[lsqbb]REDACTED[rsqbb] reporting competitors.
50. The ZIP codes in which the reporting carriers in Atlanta
offered facilities-based competition were those with the highest
average business establishment densities. This is reflected in Table 5,
which compares average business establishment density between ZIP code
areas in which reporting carriers compete and ZIP codes areas in which
they do not (and includes similar data for the Miami and Norfolk MSAs).
Because the data submissions that serve as the basis for Table 5 were
voluntary, the reporting competitors do not necessarily represent all
competition in the three MSAs discussed above, and it is possible that
competitors have higher market shares than our data show. However,
Table 5 does not show market shares, but rather the geographic breadth
of coverage by competitors within the MSA. Further analysis of these
data indicates that the reporting carriers had a tendency to enter the
same areas within the MSA. We have no reason to believe that the
competitors' focus on high business establishment density indicated by
these data would change if we were able to obtain data from any other
competitive providers with access facilities in the Atlanta, Miami and
Norfolk MSAs. Thus, despite the fact that our competitive showings
rules were designed to predict competitive entry across an MSA, these
data suggest a strong tendency for competitive LECs to deploy channel
termination facilities to end users only in ZIP codes with the highest
density of business establishments.
Table 5--Average Business Establishment Density in MSAs by ZIP Codes With vs. Without Facilities-Based
Competition From Reporting Carriers
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Average Average of
establishment establishment
density in ZIP density in ZIP
Number of ZIP Percent of ZIP codes with codes without
codes in MSA codes in MSA reported reported
MSA and status of incumbent provider with reported with reported facilities- facilities-
facilities- facilities- based based
based based competition competition
competition competition (units: estab. (units: estab.
per square per square
mile) mile)
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Atlanta, GA (2000 AT&T/BellSouth Phase II 59 40 175 41
Pricing Flexibility)...........................
Miami, FL (2000 AT&T/BellSouth Phase II)........ 41 31 390 181
Norfolk, VA (2001 Verizon Phase II)............. 36 78 106 59
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
51. Chart 6 displays the distribution of establishment density for
ZIP codes in the three MSAs of Table 5. The distribution at the top of
Chart 6 is for ZIP codes in which no reporting carrier offered
facilities-based competition for end-user channel terminations and the
distribution at the bottom is for ZIP codes in which one or more
reporting carriers did offer facilities-based competition for end-user
channel terminations. The chart indicates that the reporting carriers
had a greater tendency to offer competition in ZIP codes with business
establishment density greater than 100 establishments per square mile
than they did in ZIP codes with lower establishment densities. Based on
an analysis of the individual ZIP code areas, the probability that the
carriers' location decisions in these metropolitan areas were not tied
to business establishment density is exceedingly small. The findings
from this analysis are consistent with other evidence in the record.
[[Page 57515]]
[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TR18SE12.073
52. The fact that there may be other competitors in these MSAs that
are not reflected in our data, that more competitors may enter in the
future, or that current competitors may build out to other parts of the
MSA with high business density does not diminish our finding that
competitors typically enter in areas of high business establishment
density. Commenters rightly point out that we do not have comprehensive
facilities data for the MSAs above. We recognize the limitations of our
existing data set and, as described below, we intend to collect
additional data in the coming months that will help inform our
analysis. However, even this partial data provides insight into where
competitors choose to enter within an MSA, and reinforces evidence we
have received in this record.
53. Incumbent LECs generally concede that competitors have focused
on areas in which demand for special access services is very
concentrated. As SBC noted:
Demand for special access services is highly concentrated in a
relatively small number of dense urban wire centers and ex-urban
wire centers containing office parks and other campus environments.
Indeed, more than [REDACTED] percent of SBC's special access demand
in Phase II MSAs is concentrated in [REDACTED] percent of its wire
centers. To meet this demand, competitors have deployed myriad
competitive facilities--including fiber connected directly to end-
user premises--in markets across SBC's territory, particularly in
dense, metropolitan areas and large campus environments.
Verizon states that more than 80 percent of demand is generated in 8
percent of its wire centers, ``enabling competitors to address a large
portion of demand through targeted investments.'' This is consistent
with the Commission's earlier finding that communities within an MSA
share a center of commerce, but not necessarily common economic
characteristics relating to telecommunications deployment. This record
also demonstrates that demand exists for special access services
outside of these areas and it raises concerns regarding the
availability of competitive alternatives to meet such demand.
54. Some commenters also allege that extending new facilities is
sufficiently easy that competitors could reach all parts of an MSA if
warranted even if they only have facilities in part of an MSA today.
SBC, for example, states that a large percentage of its demand for DS1
and DS3 services runs within 1,000 feet, or about three city blocks, of
existing alternative fiber. Thus, incumbent LECs argue that potential
competition exists throughout an MSA even if competitive facilities are
only present in a small area. In contrast, competitive carriers assert
that entry is far more difficult than incumbents describe in the
record. Such commenters state that, as compared to incumbent providers
who have achieved economies of scope and scale in the provision of
telecommunications services, it is not economical for competitors to
deploy their own facilities to serve all special access demand.
Competitive carriers note that construction costs, the costs of fiber
and electronics, backhaul costs, transaction costs involved in
negotiating with
[[Page 57516]]
suppliers, and other recurring costs such as rent, utilities, and
maintenance are typically too large to justify provisioning a building
with relatively low levels of demand. Covad and XO, for example,
estimate the costs of deploying a building lateral to be [REDACTED],
and tw telecom estimates that [REDACTED]. Commenters, including Covad,
XO, BT Americas, and tw telecom, also point to important barriers to
entry, including the delays in or impossibility of securing municipal
franchise agreements, rights-of-way agreements, building access
agreements, and building and zoning permits.
55. We need not resolve this controversy here, however, for data
provided by incumbent LECs demonstrate that, even if competitors could
easily deploy fiber to serve customer demand within 1,000 feet of
incumbents' facilities, many parts of an MSA would still not be served
by competitive fiber. For instance, a 2007 AT&T map depicting
competitive fiber deployment in the Austin, Texas MSA appears to
indicate that, out of the 24 AT&T wire centers in the MSA, competitive
fiber does not extend to [REDACTED]. Maps submitted by SBC in 2005
provide similar data. For instance, SBC estimates that in the San Diego
MSA, [REDACTED]. This cuts against assertions that the majority of
special access demand could be easily and quickly served by proximate
competitive alternatives.
d. Analysis of Multi-Incumbent LEC MSAs Also Suggests That MSAs Do Not
Correspond to the Scope of Entry
56. As discussed above, the Commission selected the MSA because it
decided the MSA best reflected the scope of competitive entry. If our
rules operated in a manner consistent with our predictions, it should
follow that uniform relief would generally be granted when two or more
price cap LECs operate in the same MSA. That has not proven to be the
case. For example, in the Evansville, Indiana MSA, BellSouth has 4 wire
centers and Ameritech has 13. In 2001, Ameritech qualified for Phase I
pricing flexibility. In contrast, BellSouth met the higher competitive
showings requirements for Phase II pricing flexibility one year later.
Likewise, in 2002, Verizon satisfied the requirements for Phase II
pricing flexibility for its 2 wire centers in the Bridgeport-Stamford-
Norwalk, Connecticut MSA. Two years later, SNET was only able to get
Phase I pricing flexibility, based on revenue of 9 out of its 22 wire
centers in the same MSA. In the total of 12 MSAs in which we granted
pricing flexibility to more than one provider within the MSA, our data
shows instances of inconsistent grants of pricing flexibility in nine.
These data reinforce our conclusion that competitive conditions can
vary significantly across an MSA.
e. Billing Practices May Not Be Indicative of Competitive Entry
57. It is not clear, based on our existing record, that incumbent
LEC billing practices lead to consistent pricing across an MSA.
Commenters, in particular incumbent LECs, argue that special access
pricing is generally not tied to a small geographic market, but rather
pricing is uniform throughout an MSA or larger geographic region. Thus,
because tariffs typically encompass an MSA or larger geographic region,
incumbents assert that prices are constrained across that whole area,
regardless of the presence of competition in any individual location.
Such commenters also argue that it is administratively burdensome for
the Commission to assess whether competition exists for granular
geographic markets, and that it would be onerous for carriers to
implement pricing flexibility for individual buildings or wire centers.
Thus, AT&T, for example, states that the current pricing flexibility
rules strike ``a reasonable balance between the costs and benefits of
identifying with greater granularity those geographic areas where LECs
face competition from rivals with sunk investments and the
administrative manageability of pricing flexibility rules.''
58. There also is evidence, however, that incumbent LEC billing
practices may not be uniform across MSAs. Price cap LECs have the
authority to set prices in zones within an MSA or the non-MSA portions
of a study area. In the Pricing Flexibility Order, the Commission
amended Sec. 69.123 of its rules to permit incumbent price cap LECs to
deaverage geographically their rates for access services in the
trunking basket, and to allow price cap incumbent LECs to define the
scope and number of density zones. The Commission noted that
``averaging across large geographic areas distorts the operation of
markets in high-cost areas because it requires incumbent LECs to offer
services in those areas at prices substantially lower than their costs
of providing those services.'' However, by granting incumbent LECs the
flexibility to ``choose the number of zones and the criteria for
establishing zone boundaries, they are more likely to establish
reasonable and efficient pricing zones.'' The record indicates that
price cap LECs do, in at least some cases, take advantage of Sec.
69.123's geographic deaveraging provisions. It is therefore possible
for price cap LECs to charge different prices in, for example, rural
and urban areas within an MSA or non-MSA portion of a study area, and
the record indicates that carriers may engage in this practice.
59. Moreover, in Phase I and Phase II pricing flexibility areas,
carriers can and do offer contract tariffs to special access customers
on an individualized basis. The record indicates that such contract
terms are rarely, if ever, adopted by other special access purchasers.
Thus, whether special access pricing is, in fact, disciplined across a
broad geographic area as claimed by incumbent LECs remains an open
question.
f. Changes to MSAs Impact Non-MSA Rules
60. Price cap LECs seeking pricing flexibility under our rules in a
non-MSA area must make competitive showings throughout the entire non-
MSA portion of a study area, rather than a Rural Service Area or
smaller geography. The Commission justified its adoption of the non-MSA
as the appropriate geographic area because it predicted that
``competitive entry into rural areas [would] be less concentrated than
in urban areas.'' Embarq contends that our decision to use the non-MSA
parts of a study area, instead of an RSA, has made it impossible for
Embarq to obtain relief in Missouri despite the presence of
competition. Though Embarq's situation may be indicative of a problem
specific to our choice of adopting the non-MSA, any changes we find to
be warranted with respect to the MSA, as discussed above, must be
reflected by corresponding changes to non-MSA areas.
61. Moreover, the record in this proceeding suggests that the
Pricing Flexibility Order's prediction that competition in rural areas
would not be concentrated was incorrect. A review of our grants of
pricing flexibility for channel terminations to end users in non-MSA
areas highlights problems similar to what we found in MSA areas.
Specifically, out of five of these types of grants, three were based on
high concentrations of demand. Verizon's grant in non-MSA Idaho was
based on the revenues of 3 out of 26 wire centers, and its grant for
non-MSA West Virginia was based on revenues from 8 out of 97 wire
centers. A third grant, from ACS, was based on revenues from only half
of the wire centers in non-MSA Juneau, Alaska. This suggests that, at
the time the grant of pricing flexibility was made, competitive
conditions varied greatly
[[Page 57517]]
within the non-MSA areas. Even if new competitors subsequently entered
the non-MSA, for the reasons discussed above with respect to MSAs, they
are likely to locate only in areas of high demand. Thus, the evidence
in this proceeding suggests highly concentrated competitive conditions
at the time pricing flexibility was granted. This indicates that the
Pricing Flexibility Order's prediction that competition in non-MSA
areas would be less concentrated than in urban areas may have been
incorrect.
3. The Competitive Showings Are Not as Administratively Simple as
Expected
62. In addition to the issues identified above, our experience
shows that our rules, which were intended first and foremost to be
straightforward and simple to administer, are not. Specifically, in
adopting the Pricing Flexibility Order, the Commission concluded that
using MSA-based rules would be simpler and less expensive to administer
than rules based on other geographies or regimes that might create a
``more finely-tuned picture of competitive conditions.'' However, the
rules have not been as administratively simple or easy to verify as the
Commission anticipated, nor does it appear that they have provided
bright-line guidance to industry. We therefore choose to redirect our
efforts to conducting a more complete market analysis, as discussed in
greater detail in Section 0 below.
63. Previous pricing flexibility petitions demonstrate that our
rules have failed to provide a clear-cut guide to industry. For
example, Sec. 22.909(a) of our rules define MSAs for pricing
flexibility, as ``* * * 306 areas * * * defined by the Office of
Management and Budget, as modified by the FCC.'' Because OMB changes
the list of MSAs and component counties, as discussed above, Sec.
22.909 of the Commission's rules refers to a static list, based on data
from the 1980 Census. Nonetheless, the fact that our rules refer to
areas in which to make a competitive showing as ``MSAs'' has apparently
created some confusion among petitioners, resulting in petitions
containing data calculated over different MSA definitions. For example,
Pacific Bell submitted a petition for pricing flexibility in the San
Diego and Sacramento MSAs based on the list referenced in Sec. 22.909
of our rules. In contrast, Embarq and Cincinnati Bell based their 2007
pricing flexibility petitions on MSAs drawn in accordance with a
``Metropolitan Areas (1993)'' map, located on the Commission's Web
site, that provides a detailed description of how the map includes MSAs
as defined by OMB. However, because the 1993 MSAs were more recently
constructed and based on 1990 Census data, the component counties that
make up each MSA are often different from those in the MSA list
referenced in Sec. 22.909 of our rules. Thus, our supposedly bright-
line rules have failed to provide guidance to sophisticated firms such
as Embarq and Cincinnati Bell.
64. Moreover, our competitive showings are ambiguous and require
time-intensive review and policy decisions by Commission staff. In
order to fulfill the requirements of the revenue-based competitive
showings, a petitioner must: (a) Provide a list of wire centers within
that MSA; and (b) calculate revenues based on that number. However, our
rules do not specify how to determine whether a wire center belongs to
a specific MSA, nor do they provide enough specifics as to what
revenues should be included. Therefore, as applied, petitioners are
making these determinations using different methodologies. For example,
Southwestern Bell determined which wire centers belonged to the
Amarillo and St. Louis MSAs based on ``the Collocation Implementation,
Collocation Point of Contact and Tracking Database,'' which includes
wire center information for all MSAs. It excluded from its revenue
calculations those revenues derived from Individual Case Basis (ICB)
arrangements, i.e., ``the carrier practice of providing a particular
service in response to a specific request from a customer under
individualized rates, terms, and conditions.'' An ICB arrangement may
involve services directly related to the provision of special access
services, such as special conditioning of a line. In contrast, in a
2008 petition, Windstream acknowledged that some of its wire centers
located outside the applied-for MSA may serve locations inside the MSA
boundary. Therefore, based on its own engineering maps, ``Windstream
calculated the exchange area that fell within the MSA. If the area
calculated exceeded 50 percent of the total area of the wire center,
the wire center was assigned to the MSA.'' In contrast to Southwestern
Bell's system of calculating revenues, Windstream included ICB revenues
in its revenue calculations. Thus, in order to properly evaluate
whether these petitioners have fulfilled the requirements of our rules,
which are silent on these issues, Commission staff would have to do a
thorough review of the company's internal records, exercise an
extensive amount of independent judgment, and make some significant
policy decisions as to whether each company's interpretation of our
rules are consistent with the terms of the Pricing Flexibility Order.
C. Shortcomings of Competitive Showings Based Exclusively on
Collocation
65. Significant questions also exist about the reliability of
collocation as a proxy for facilities-based competition in end user
channel terminations. Charges for special access generally are divided
into channel termination charges and channel mileage charges. Channel
termination charges recover the costs of facilities between the
customer's premises and the LEC end office and the costs of facilities
between the IXC POP and the LEC serving wire center. Channel mileage
charges recover the costs of facilities (also known as interoffice
facilities) between the serving wire center and the LEC end office
serving the end user. In the Pricing Flexibility Order, the Commission
found that pricing flexibility for channel terminations between a LEC
end office and a customer premises required a higher threshold showing
than pricing flexibility for other dedicated transport and special
access services. In reaching this determination, the Commission
acknowledged that the economics of channel terminations between the LEC
office and the customer premises make it more costly for new entrants
to compete in that product market.
1. Rationale for Adopting Collocation as the Sole Indicator of
Competition
66. The competitive showings require price cap LECs to offer
evidence of collocation by ``competitors that use transport provided by
a transport provider other than the incumbent LEC'' for granting
pricing flexibility for special access and dedicated transport. The
Commission considered that the competitive showings reasonably balanced
two goals: ``(1) Having a clear picture of competitive conditions in
the MSA, so that we can be certain that there is irreversible
investment sufficient to discourage exclusionary pricing behavior; and
(2) adopting an easily verifiable, bright-line test to avoid excessive
administrative burdens.'' The Commission found that collocation was a
``reliable indicator of sunk investment by competitors'' in dedicated
transport and special access services other than channel terminations
because it demonstrated a financial investment by the competitor in
establishing facilities in that wire center.
[[Page 57518]]
67. With respect to channel terminations, the Commission
acknowledged that ``collocation by competitors does not provide direct
evidence of sunk investment by competitors in channel terminations
between the end office and the customer premises.'' Indeed, the
Commission recognized that ``a competitor collocating in a LEC end
office continues to rely on the LEC's facilities for the channel
termination between the end office and the customer premises, at least
initially, and thus is susceptible to exclusionary pricing behavior by
the LEC.'' The Commission predicted, however, that ``that a new market
entrant would provide channel terminations through collocation and
leased LEC facilities only on a transitional basis and [would]
eventually extend its own facilities to reach its customers.'' It thus
concluded that despite ``the shortcomings of using collocation to
measure competition for channel terminations, * * * it appears to be
the best option available to us at this time.''
2. More Recent Evidence Suggests That Collocation May Produce an
Unreliable Picture of Competitive Conditions
68. Evidence submitted to the Commission since 1999 calls into
question the Commission's prediction that collocators would eventually
build their own channel terminations to end users. By the end of 2005,
six years after the adoption of the Pricing Flexibility Order, SBC
Communications, Inc. (SBC) had obtained pricing flexibility for channel
terminations to end users in 67 MSAs. That same year, it acquired AT&T
Corporation. Both the Commission and the Antitrust Division of the U.S.
Department of Justice (``the Division'') approved the transaction,
subject to several concessions, including divestitures. Despite SBC's
success in obtaining pricing flexibility in many MSAs, the Division's
antitrust investigation concluded that ``for the vast majority of
commercial buildings in its territory, SBC is the only carrier that
owns a last-mile connection to the building.'' That same year, the
Commission's review of Qwest's petition for forbearance in Omaha,
Nebraska showed that some buildout to end users had occurred, but only
in 9 out of 24 of Qwest's wire centers in the Omaha MSA. This was three
years after Qwest had obtained Phase II pricing flexibility in the
Omaha MSA, based on the revenues of 11 wire centers (8 of which
overlapped with the 9 wire centers with buildout to end users). In
2006, the U.S. Government Accountability Office (``GAO'') analyzed 16
metropolitan areas in which the Commission had granted pricing
flexibility and found that facilities-based competitors served fewer
than 6 percent of buildings with at least a DS1-level of demand. In
2010, Qwest noted in its transfer of control application with
CenturyLink that ``it is Qwest's practice generally to use the
facilities of other carriers when it sells services to enterprise
customers in locations outside of its service territory.''
69. Commenters' pleadings also suggest that collocation has not
always developed into facilities-based competition. As evidence to
support its assertion that our predictions about collocation were
inaccurate, TW Telecom relied on data supplied by Verizon to assert
that between 1996 and 2004, non-incumbent LEC channel termination
buildout to commercial buildings increased from 24,000 buildings to
approximately 31,467 buildings (a change of 7,467), in contrast to the
``millions of buildings served by incumbent LEC fiber.'' In 2005,
WilTel estimated that competitors had deployed to 25,000 buildings,
whereas Sprint asserted in 2007 that only 22,000 buildings had
competing connections. Moreover, TW Telecom states that, as of a 2003
Commission finding, competitors serve only three to five percent of
commercial buildings nationwide. It also submitted evidence that it
contends shows that, four years after Verizon had obtained Phase I
pricing flexibility in the New York MSA for channel terminations to end
users, competitors served fewer than [lsqbb]REDACTED[rsqbb] of 220,000
buildings in New York City. Its evidence also showed that, in Chicago,
where Ameritech had obtained pricing flexibility for channel
terminations in 2003, competitors connected to only 429 out of 241,000
commercial buildings.
70. Commenters also argue that the mere installation of third party
facilities within wire centers does not equate to competition by
collocators because in some cases they are not being used to provide
competitive service. For example, in its oppositions to two incumbent
LEC petitions for pricing flexibility, AT&T argued that it never used
the facilities it had installed in some of the wire centers listed in
the petitions, and it was therefore erroneously identified as a
competitive collocator. However, the competitive showing rules do not
require incumbent LECs to show that collocation facilities are being
used, but only that they exist in the wire center. Moreover, Sprint
argues that collocation ``is indicative not that the competitor has
placed its own facilities into buildings but rather that it has
dependence upon the incumbent's facility.''
71. We acknowledge that this evidence is limited. The Commission's
recent attempts to obtain more robust facilities data through voluntary
production have provided useful, but incomplete, data. Nonetheless, the
evidence we do have suggests our predictions were inaccurate and that
the accuracy of the use of collocations as a proxy for actual or
potential competition warrants further investigation. We therefore
intend to issue a data request that will require carriers to submit the
data we need to test the accuracy of the predictions we made about
collocation in the Pricing Flexibility Order.
3. Existence of Non-Collocation Based Competition Does Not Undercut the
Need To Suspend Grants of New Pricing Flexibility Petitions
72. Several commenters argue that relying exclusively on
collocation is flawed because it undercounts entry by non-collocating
firms who have built their own facilities. We agree, but because we
lack reliable data on the extent or location of this competition, it
does not change our conclusion that new pricing flexibility petitions
should be suspended at this time.
73. Several commenters discuss growing competition from non-
collocating competitors, such as cable. For example, Verizon claims
that the competitive showings preclude it from obtaining pricing
flexibility commensurate to the level of competition they claim exists
in Los Angeles, Boston, New York, Philadelphia, and Washington, DC,
because our rules do not account for several non-collocating firms that
Verizon's research indicates have operations in those areas. AT&T has
similar complaints for its operations in Chicago, Dallas, Houston,
Detroit, San Diego and St. Louis, contending that it has lost special
access business to cable firms in many instances. Embarq asserts that
it too has lost business to a competitive LEC, Cox Cable, that does not
collocate in Las Vegas, Nevada, and Fort Walton Beach and Ocala,
Florida. Price cap LECs also criticize the rules for excluding
competitors that collocate at ``collocation hotels,'' as opposed to
price cap LEC wire centers. Thus, the record indicates that at times
the rules may prevent price cap LECs from obtaining partial or full
pricing flexibility because they do not account for competition
sufficient to discipline rates from facilities-based competitors.
74. We agree. As the Commission stated when it adopted its
competitive
[[Page 57519]]
showings rules, it has ``long recognized that it should allow incumbent
LECs progressively greater pricing flexibility as they face increasing
competition'' and wanted to ensure that its ``regulations do not unduly
interfere with the development and operation of these markets as
competition develops.'' It would be inconsistent with this approach if
we inappropriately subjected price cap LECs to unnecessary regulations,
despite the emergence of competition that bright-line rules are unable
to detect. We therefore agree to undertake a robust competition
analysis that takes these factors into account, as described below.
75. Moreover, there is currently no evidence in the record
addressing the relationship, if any, between collocation levels and the
presence of non-collocated competitors. Such data would assist in
testing incumbents' claims that they have lost business to non-
collocating competitors with their own fiber. We intend to obtain
evidence on this point in order to conduct the robust competition
analysis described below.
IV. Grants of Pricing Flexibility Are Suspended
76. As set forth in sections 0 and III.C above, there is compelling
evidence that the competitive showings adopted in 1999 have not worked
as intended, and that our pricing flexibility rules are simultaneously
preventing grants of pricing flexibility in areas that likely are
competitive and allowing grants of pricing flexibility in areas where
it is not appropriate to do so. While we today initiate the process of
developing a better way to identify areas where special access
regulatory relief is appropriate, it would not serve the public
interest to allow continued grants of pricing flexibility under our old
rules. We therefore act in this section to temporarily suspend the
operation of our competitive showing rules pending completion of our
inquiry.
A. Suspension of Competitive Showing Rules for Channel Terminations
77. Based on the evidence in the record as discussed in subsections
0 and III.0 above, we suspend further grants of pricing flexibility on
the basis of our existing pricing flexibility rules. Generally, the
Commission's rules may be suspended for good cause shown. In light of
the significant problems identified with grants of regulatory relief at
the MSA level, continuing to grant relief under the current framework
would run precisely the risk that the Commission sought to avoid in the
Pricing Flexibility Order: ``Granting pricing flexibility over such a
large geographic area would increase the likelihood of exclusionary
behavior by incumbent LECs by giving them flexibility in areas where
competitors have not yet made irreversible investment in facilities.''
Given our finding that the special access pricing flexibility triggers
are not operating as predicted by the Commission, our action here
suspending the application of those rules while we consider possible
new regulatory approaches is necessary in the public interest. In
addition, it is consistent with our ``continuing obligation to practice
reasoned decision making'' under the APA. Indeed, this continuing
obligation to practice reasoned decision making and revisit our rules
is especially relevant where our predictive judgments do not
materialize. The record indicates that the 1999 competitive showing
rules are both over-inclusive and under-inclusive, thereby resulting in
grants of pricing flexibility to broad geographic areas (i.e., MSAs)
based on small pockets of concentrated demand, or denials of pricing
flexibility where competitive alternatives are not recognized by the
existing rules. Moreover, there is evidence that collocations--while
perhaps ``the best option available'' to the Commission at the time--
are not a reliable indicator of the presence of actual or potential
competition in the provision of channel terminations.
78. The Commission's rules provide that petitions for pricing
flexibility for special access services that are not denied within 90
days after the close of the pleading cycle are deemed granted. Given
the significant problems identified with our existing pricing
flexibility rules discussed above, we find that it would be
inappropriate to allow new grants of flexibility under those rules.
Thus, pursuant to rule Sec. 1.3, we find good cause to suspend the 90
day deadline in rule Sec. 1.774(f)(1) and do so on our own motion. We
therefore amend our rules as set forth in Appendix A.
B. Suspension of Competitive Showing Rules for Non-Channel Termination
Special Access
79. As noted above, the staff analysis of specific data
highlighting problems with the MSA was restricted to channel
terminations to end users. Nonetheless, the record also indicates a
lack of ``reasonably similar'' competitive conditions within an MSA for
dedicated transport. As discussed above, both Verizon and SBC concede
that special access demand--for all categories of special access
services--is extremely concentrated. Fiber maps that they submitted
throughout this proceeding, which include both dedicated transport and
channel terminations, highlight that fact. In 2007, AT&T submitted
detailed maps showing competitive deployment for Atlanta, Georgia;
Miami, Florida; Columbus, Ohio; Austin, Texas and San Jose, California.
In 2012, it submitted competitive deployment maps for three of those
same MSAs (Atlanta, Miami and San Jose), as well as several other MSAs.
Though each of those maps--whether they were produced in 2007 or 2012--
display competitive fiber in the central portion of each MSA, none of
those maps show that those competitive fibers reach throughout the
MSAs. In addition, as discussed above with respect to our review of
pricing flexibility grants for channel terminations for end users, in a
significant number of the MSAs where price cap carriers have been
granted relief, a large proportion of wire centers have either no
collocations, no competitive transport, or both. This calls into
question whether our transport bright-line tests, which if met lead to
pricing flexibility being applied to the entire MSA, appropriately
distinguish where competition exists and where it does not. Further,
though the Pricing Flexibility Order noted competitive differences
among special access services, it did not make any distinctions as to
the appropriate geographic area of relief based on the type of service
at issue. Instead, the Commission adopted bright-line competitive
showings, with a uniform geographic area, for all categories of special
access service. For these reasons, we find it appropriate to
temporarily suspend our competitive showing rules for dedicated
transport.
C. Arguments Against Suspension of Rules
80. Broad Assertions Regarding Competition. Commenters assert that
the deregulatory approach of pricing flexibility, as well as the
current competitive showing rules, has been sufficient to constrain
exclusionary or predatory conduct by LECs to date. For example,
Verizon, Qwest, AT&T, and CenturyLink assert that special access prices
have fallen since the adoption of pricing flexibility, and that special
access outputs have increased. CenturyLink states that special access
must be considered in the broader context, as incumbent LECs have been
facing substantial business challenges. Thus, absent evidence of a
fundamental failure in the current pricing flexibility rules--which
commenters believe has not been shown in the record--the
[[Page 57520]]
Commission should not substantially revise or eliminate those rules.
81. There is insufficient evidence in the record upon which to base
general or categorical conclusions regarding the competitiveness of the
special access market. As an initial matter, it is not clear how the
Commission should consider arguments that market definitions are not
relevant because the undefined market is highly competitive. Such
arguments would have us presume the outcome at the heart of our inquiry
prior to conducting any analysis of market conditions. Categorical
assertions about competitiveness are not an adequate basis upon which
we can base grants of pricing flexibility, particularly in light of the
problems with the current competitive showing requirements, as well as
the potentially conflicting evidence in the record about the changes in
special access prices in Phase I and Phase II pricing flexibility
areas. While incumbent LECs assert that special access prices have
fallen in pricing flexibility areas, competitors state that prices,
particularly in areas granted Phase II relief, have increased. This
evidence is inconclusive; thus, we do not pass judgment on these
assertions in this Report and Order. However, given the problems
associated with the 1999 competitive showing rules, we do believe that
the record contains sufficient disputed evidence to warrant further
scrutiny by the Commission. The current competitive showing rules
provide only a limited inquiry into the state of competition in a given
market, a fact that commenters, including incumbent LECs, concede.
82. Moreover, we do not agree that WorldCom or the Pricing
Flexibility Order compel us to maintain the collocation-based
competitive showing rules or a similar standard. In WorldCom, the court
explicitly affirmed the Commission's discretion to adopt new policy
positions, provided that it provides a reasoned analysis to support its
decisions. Further, the WorldCom court noted that, unless they are
statutorily precluded from doing so, agencies have the discretion to
make adjustments to their regulations in light of changed
circumstances. The court also held that the Commission did not err in
basing its policymaking on ``predictive forecasts,'' because the
Commission's adoption of the competitive showing rules was a reasonable
prediction of how competition for special access might develop in the
future. Throughout this Report and Order, we identify the problems
associated with the current pricing flexibility rules and explain why
suspending the current competitive showings while we conduct a market
analysis will enable us to identify a replacement for the competitive
showing rules that will allow us to more effectively evaluate requests
for pricing flexibility. Thus, we disagree with commenters who assert
that precedent requires a different result.
83. Data Collection Necessary. We do not agree with commenters that
it is necessary to collect additional data prior to suspending our
rules. As discussed in section 0, above, the existing record contains
sufficient evidence to call the continued viability of the collocation-
based competitive showing rules into question. We therefore will not
allow the inefficiencies resulting from those rules to go unaddressed
until we are able to obtain a more extensive data set. In our view, it
is appropriate to suspend the competitive showing rules adopted in the
Pricing Flexibility Order while we undertake a competition analysis to
assist us in determining how to assess the presence of actual and
potential competition sufficient to discipline special access prices.
D. Changes in Regulatory Relief During Development of New Rules
84. We note that parties may still take steps to alter the
regulatory status of special access services during the pendency of
this proceeding. As commenters have noted, the Commission has the power
to resolve allegations of unjust or unreasonable rates, terms and
conditions through the complaint process in the Act, rather than
through a rulemaking proceeding. Parties also may petition for
forbearance from any regulation or provision of the Act pursuant to
sec. 10 thereof, or seek a waiver of our rules. The availability of
these forms of recourse provides additional support for suspension of
our competitive showing rules pending development of an improved method
for providing regulatory relief.
V. Undertaking a Market Analysis for Special Access Regulatory Relief
A. Future Steps to Analyze Competition for Special Access
85. In this section, we commence a process that will enable us to
more effectively determine where regulatory relief is appropriate. In
the coming months, we will undertake a robust market analysis to assist
us in determining how best to assess the presence of actual and
potential competition for special access that is sufficient to
discipline prices. Our analysis will follow the collection of
additional data and an opportunity for public comment. As described
below, there is widespread accord in the record on the appropriateness
of collecting additional data to inform our future actions.
86. The market analysis we will undertake in the coming months may
identify reliable proxies for competition for special access services,
which we could adopt in lieu of the 1999 competitive showings. Our
analysis may also provide evidence that changes in our regulatory
approach are warranted in particular geographic areas. At this time, we
do not exhaustively specify the factors that will comprise our market
analysis: these will be subject to comment by interested parties in an
upcoming notice. We anticipate that the analysis will be a one-time
assessment of the competitive conditions in the special access market;
however, we do not foreclose the possibility that further analyses may
be needed in the future. In any event, we will issue a comprehensive
data collection order within 60 days to facilitate this market
analysis.
B. Benefits of a More Complete Market Analysis
1. A Market Analysis is Consistent With Agency and Court Precedent
87. We concur with commenters who point out that use of market
analysis in the special access context is consistent with Commission
precedent. The Commission historically has conducted an examination of
market conditions in several instances to assess competition for
telecommunications services. In a series of orders in the Competitive
Carrier proceedings, the Commission established a framework to evaluate
competition in telecommunications markets and determine whether
deregulatory treatment of certain carriers is warranted. In those
orders, the Commission performed a structural market analysis to
distinguish between ``dominant carriers,'' which ``possess market power
(i.e., the power to control price),'' and ``non-dominant carriers,''
which ``do not possess power over price.'' The Commission focused its
inquiry on certain ``clearly identifiable market features,'' including
a carrier's market share, number and size distribution of competing
firms, the nature of competitors' barriers to entry, the availability
of reasonably substitutable services, the level of demand elasticity,
and whether the firm controlled bottleneck facilities. This analysis
was designed to identify when competition is sufficient to constrain
carriers from imposing unjust, unreasonable, or unjustly or
[[Page 57521]]
unreasonably discriminatory rates, terms, and conditions, or from
acting in an anticompetitive manner. The Commission subsequently
applied the same framework to reclassify AT&T as non-dominant in the
interstate interexchange service market, finding that AT&T no longer
possessed individual market power with respect to those services.
88. In the 1997 LEC Classification Order, the Commission modified
its framework for dominance/non-dominance analyses to bring the
framework into accord with the antitrust analysis laid out in the 1992
Merger Guidelines, a precursor to the 2010 Horizontal Merger Guidelines
that are in use today. In that order, the Commission stated that the
assessment of competitive conditions requires a thorough analysis which
begins with a delineation of the relevant product and geographic
markets, and then considers market characteristics, including market
shares, the potential for the exercise of market power, and whether
potential entry would be timely, likely, and sufficient to counteract
the exercise of market power.
89. More recently, the Commission has undertaken market analysis to
assess the extent of competition in both merger proceedings and in the
evaluation of forbearance petitions. For instance, in its analysis of
the proposed AT&T/BellSouth and Verizon/MCI mergers, the Commission
considered whether the mergers would reduce existing competition, as
well as their likely effects on the market power of dominant firms in
the relevant communications markets and the mergers' effects on future
competition. Similarly, in the Qwest Phoenix Forbearance Order the
Commission employed a structural market analysis akin to that of the
Competitive Carrier cases to evaluate Qwest's petition for forbearance
from certain wholesale and retail regulations in the Phoenix, Arizona,
MSA. Additionally, a market analysis is consistent with the
investigation performed by the DOJ and FTC to assess whether a
horizontal merger could adversely impact competition in relevant
markets.
90. In the Pricing Flexibility Order, the Commission declined to
require incumbent LECs to perform a complete market analysis as part of
the carrier's application for pricing flexibility and instead, without
the benefit of a fulsome market analysis, adopted proxies for
competition that were intended to measure whether actual or potential
competition was sufficient to ensure just and reasonable rates, terms
and conditions for special access services. As discussed above and
based on the record in this proceeding, we have suspended grants of
pricing flexibility on the basis of these proxies because we find that
the geographic market over which relief is granted, MSAs, do not
correspond to the scope of competitive entry and serious question have
been raised concerning whether the presence of collocation and
competitive transport are reliable indicators of the presence of
competitive channel termination services. The process we begin today
may well assist in developing new proxies for special access
competition, which could be employed going forward to evaluate
petitions for pricing flexibility. Once we have had the opportunity to
collect and analyze additional data, we will be better positioned to
determine what specific showings price cap carriers must make in their
petitions for pricing flexibility and what information they could
submit to satisfy those showings.
2. A Market Analysis Will Provide Analytical Precision
91. Several commenters recommend that, prior to adopting a new
analytical framework, we collect competitive data to assess whether the
current competitive showing rules are a reasonably accurate proxy for
the presence of competition. Undertaking a market analysis will allow
the Commission to more precisely determine where competition exists, or
could potentially exist, and to develop better tests for regulatory
relief to replace the current collocation-based approach. For example,
as described above, some commenters observe that the collocation-based
competitive showings do not account for sources of intermodal and/or
intramodal competition that do not collocate in incumbent LEC
facilities. Other commenters raise concerns that the 1999 competitive
showing rules overlook competitors who could potentially enter the
market in the near term or in the more distant future. In contrast to
our current approach, a market analysis would seek to identify
significant current and potential market participants, and consider
their impact when assessing the level of competition in a market.
92. Several commenters state that a single market characteristic
(e.g., high special access rates or carrier revenues, large market
share) is generally not sufficient on its own to signify whether a
given market is competitive. For example, AT&T and Verizon both assert
that the Commission should not rely on market share as the basis for
concluding that a given market lacks competition, because market share
is a static measure that can understate the impact of competitive
alternatives in dynamic markets. We agree that the Commission must
conduct a more comprehensive analysis of the state of competition prior
to adopting replacement competitive proxies or making other changes to
the ways that incumbent LECs may obtain regulatory relief in the
provision of special access services. A market analysis will enable us
to make a multi-faceted assessment of competition that considers a
variety of factors, including both price and non-price effects.
Additionally, this type of fact-specific analysis is in line with
current approaches to competition policy.
3. A Market Analysis Will Foster Broadband Deployment and Competition
93. Finally, a comprehensive market analysis will help us to take
future steps to support broadband deployment and competition. In the
Qwest Phoenix Forbearance Order, the Commission found that, ``by using
the more comprehensive antitrust-based analysis that the Commission
frequently has used in past proceedings, and that the [FTC and DOJ]
regularly use to measure competition, we ensure that competition in
downstream markets is not negatively affected by premature forbearance
from regulatory obligations in upstream markets.'' Citing the National
Broadband Plan, the Commission noted that ``regulatory policies for
wholesale access affect the competitiveness of markets for retail
broadband services provided to small businesses, mobile customers and
enterprise customers.''
94. Special access circuits are a particularly important input for
carriers' broadband service offerings. As the National Broadband Plan
found, the costs associated with purchasing special access circuits can
be a significant expense that impacts a carrier's ability to provide
affordable broadband service, particularly to smaller, rural
communities.
95. A market analysis will enable us to ensure that appropriate
regulatory relief is granted in those markets where competitive
conditions justify it. For example, we expect that our analysis will
aid in determining whether purchasers can obtain special access
circuits at just and reasonable prices. This inquiry could provide
insight into challenges that carriers may face in deploying broadband
and what actions, if any, are needed to respond to those challenges.
[[Page 57522]]
4. Factors to be Considered in Market Analysis
96. Some commenters, in particular incumbent LECs, recommend
specific factors or considerations they believe the Commission should
include in a market analysis. We address several of these
recommendations below.
a. Analysis Must Be Forward-Looking and Consider Various Sources of
Competition
97. As detailed below, commenters state that any market analysis we
conduct must be forward-looking and account for significant competitors
in a market. We agree.
98. In our view, a comprehensive market analysis will best
facilitate a complete inquiry into the existence of competition in a
given market, including sources of intermodal and intramodal
competition, potential market entrants, uncommitted entrants, carriers
that self-supply their own special access, and non-facilities-based
competitors. This analysis also will consider the impact of competitors
that do not collocate in an incumbent's wire center.
99. For instance, the 2010 Horizontal Merger Guidelines contain a
detailed process employed to identify participants in the relevant
market. Pursuant to the 2010 Horizontal Merger Guidelines, an
identification of market participants includes all firms that currently
earn revenues in the relevant market. A firm may be considered to be a
market participant even if it does not currently earn revenues, but it
is ``committed to entering the market in the near future,'' or if the
firm is not a current producer in the relevant market, but ``would very
likely provide rapid supply responses with direct competitive impact in
the event of a [small but significant and non-transitory increase in
price (SSNIP)], without incurring significant sunk costs.'' Thus, in
those instances where a competitor, such as a cable or fixed wireless
provider, can quickly enter the market and respond to customer demand,
a market analysis would enable us to consider the likely impact of that
entry on competition.
100. Moreover, a market analysis allows for specific, economically
rigorous, and factually specific inquiries regarding potential
competition, a factor that price cap LECs such as Verizon and AT&T
contend should be included in any framework we adopt. A market analysis
of potential competition assesses whether a firm is perceived to be a
potential competitor, exerting a price-constraining effect on firms
currently participating in the market, even though it is not currently
participating in the market. We agree with commenters that our analysis
of competitive conditions should incorporate an assessment of potential
competition. We also agree that barriers to market entry should be
considered. Entry is an important consideration in a structural
analysis, as the exercise of market power is unlikely where entry
barriers are low and incumbents cannot profitably raise price or
otherwise reduce competition to a level below that of a competitive
market. In the past, the Commission has considered potential
competition and barriers to entry as part of its market analysis.
101. Further, we concur with commenters that the multi-faceted and
forward-looking analysis of competition we will undertake would be
inadequate if it focused solely on market share or building counts. By
examining factors such as the potential for competitive effects, market
entry, and potential competition, a market analysis is a forward-
looking alternative to the current competitive showing rules or any
like standard. That being said, we must carefully balance the benefits
of relying on solid, if historical data, against the risks associated
with placing too much weight on speculative data sources. We will
continue to consider our future data collection needs with these points
in mind.
b. Approach That Enhances Consumer Welfare
102. We agree with commenters who assert that the Commission must
conduct its market analysis in light of its broader objectives for the
telecommunications industry. For example, Verizon notes that pricing
flexibility was among several deregulatory actions taken by the
Commission in the 1990s with the goal of encouraging innovation, cost
savings, and efficiencies.
103. The major purpose of the 1996 Act was to establish ``a pro-
competitive, deregulatory national policy framework.'' Indeed, among
its primary goals were ``opening the local exchange and exchange access
markets to competitive entry'' and ``promoting increased competition in
telecommunications markets that are already open to competition,
including the long-distance services market.'' We undertake an
analytical process to assess the level of competition in the special
access market with these goals in mind. For example, our analysis may
indicate that further regulatory relief is warranted in areas where
competition exists, but is not captured by the current competitive
proxies. As detailed above, the competitive showings adopted in the
Pricing Flexibility Order are both over- and under-inclusive, resulting
in inaccurate assessments of whether actual and potential competition
is sufficient to constrain special access prices in the areas granted
relief. Indeed, given the unreliable nature of the competitive showing
requirements adopted in 1999, we believe a market analysis will aid us
in granting deregulation in areas where actual and potential
competition is sufficient to constrain prices. A nuanced market
analysis will also allow us to better balance the potential costs of
regulating too heavily against the potential harms of failing to
undertake appropriate regulation where it is needed.
c. Dominance/Non-Dominance Classification
104. Finally, incumbent LECs assert that special access pricing
flexibility should not be treated as akin to the non-dominance analyses
undertaken by the Commission in the Competitive Carrier proceeding.
Further, AT&T argues that, under a non-dominance framework, upon a
finding that an incumbent lacked market power, the Commission would
have to reclassify the carrier as non-dominant and relieve its dominant
carrier obligations. We agree with AT&T that, once we have performed a
broader evaluation of competitive conditions, our analysis may show
that a carrier classified as dominant does not possess market power as
defined in the Competitive Carrier proceeding for a particular special
access service in a geographic area. In that case, the Commission may
ultimately conclude that it is appropriate to grant regulatory relief
in the form of non-dominance treatment for the particular service and
geographic area. We will determine at a future date what criteria the
Commission will consider to assess whether a finding of non-dominance
for special access service is warranted in a given area.
VI. Procedural Matters
A. Paperwork Reduction Act Analysis
105. This document does not contain new or modified information
collection requirements subject to the Paperwork Reduction Act of 1995
(PRA), Public Law 104-13. In addition, therefore, it does not contain
any new or modified information collection burden for small business
concerns with fewer than 25 employees, pursuant to the Small Business
Paperwork Relief Act of 2002, Public Law 107-198, see 44 U.S.C.
3506(c)(4).
[[Page 57523]]
B. Final Regulatory Flexibility Certification
106. As required by the Regulatory Flexibility Act (RFA), an
Initial Regulatory Flexibility Analysis (IRFA) was incorporated into
the 2005 Special Access NPRM. The Commission sought written public
comment on the possible significant economic impact on small entities
regarding the proposals addressed in the 2005 Special Access NPRM,
including comments on the IRFA.
107. As required by sec. 603 of the RFA, the Commission has
prepared a Final Regulatory Flexibility Certification (FRFC) of the
expected impact on small entities of the requirements adopted in the
Report and Order, which is set forth in Appendix B of the Report and
Order. The Commission will send a copy of the Report and Order,
including the FRFC, to the Chief Counsel for Advocacy of the Small
Business Administration.
C. Congressional Review Act
108. The Commission will send a copy of this Report and Order to
Congress and the Government Accountability Office pursuant to the
Congressional Review Act.
II. Ordering Clauses
109. Accordingly, it is ordered that pursuant to sections 1, 4(i),
4(j), and 201-205 of the Communications Act of 1934, as amended, 47
U.S.C. 151, 154(i), 154(j), 201, 202, 203, 204, 205, this Report and
Order is adopted.
110. It is further ordered that part 1 of the Commission's rules is
amended as set forth in the final rules, and such rule amendments shall
be effective October 18, 2012.
111. It is further ordered that Sec. 1.774(f)(1) of the
Commission's rules, 47 CFR 1.774(f)(1), is suspended until the
amendments set forth in the final rules are effective.
112. It is further ordered that, pursuant to Sec. Sec. 1.4(b)(1)
and 1.103(a) of the Commission's rules, 47 CFR 1.4(b)(1), 1.103(a),
this Report and Order is effective upon release.
113. It is further ordered that the Commission will send a copy of
this Report and Order to Congress and the Government Accountability
Office pursuant to the Congressional Review Act, see 5 U.S.C.
801(a)(1)(A).
114. It is further ordered that the Commission's Consumer and
Governmental Affairs Bureau, Reference Information Center, shall send a
copy of this Report and Order, including the Final Regulatory
Flexibility Certification, to the Chief Counsel for Advocacy of the
Small Business Administration.
List of Subjects in 47 CFR Part 1
Administrative practice and procedure, Communications common
carriers, Telecommunications.
Federal Communications Commission
Marlene H. Dortch,
Secretary.
Final Rule
For the reasons discussed in the preamble, the Federal
Communications Commission amends 47 CFR Part 1 as follows:
PART 1--PRACTICE AND PROCEDURE
0
1. The authority citation for part 1 continues to read as follows:
Authority: 15 U.S.C. 79, et seq., 47 U.S.C. 151, 154(i),
154(j), 155, 157, 225, 227, 303(r) and 309.
Sec. 1.774 [Amended]
0
2. In Sec. 1.774, remove and reserve paragraph (f)(1).
[FR Doc. 2012-23020 Filed 9-17-12; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6712-01-P