United States v. Morgan Stanley; Public Comments and Response on Proposed Final Judgment, 15125-15139 [2012-5952]
Download as PDF
Federal Register / Vol. 77, No. 50 / Wednesday, March 14, 2012 / Notices
the United States will cause to be
transferred a total of $71,000 from the
Judgment Fund at the United States
Treasury to the EPA Hazardous
Substance Superfund.
The Department of Justice will receive
for a period of thirty (30) days from the
date of this publication comments
relating to the proposed Consent Decree.
Comments should be addressed to the
Assistant Attorney General,
Environment and Natural Resources
Division, and either emailed to
pubcomment-ees.enrd@usdoj.gov or
mailed to P.O. Box 7611, U.S.
Department of Justice, Washington, DC
20044–7611, and should refer to this
case: United States v. FMC Corporation,
Civil Action No. 2:11–cv–00699, D.J.
Ref. 90–11–2–09066/1.
During the public comment period,
the Consent Decree may be examined on
the following Department of Justice Web
site, https://www.usdoj.gov/enrd/
Consent_Decrees.html. A copy of the
proposed Consent Decree may also be
obtained by mail from the Consent
Decree Library, P.O. Box 7611, U.S.
Department of Justice, Washington, DC
20044–7611 or by faxing or emailing a
request to ‘‘Consent Decree Copy’’
(EESCDCopy.ENRD@usdoj.gov), fax no.
(202) 514–0097, phone confirmation no.
(202) 514–5271. In requesting a copy
from the Consent Decree Library, please
enclose a check payable to the ‘‘U.S.
Treasury’’ or, if by email or fax, forward
a check in that amount to the Consent
Decree Library at the stated address, in
the following amount (25 cents per page
reproduction cost): $6.50 for the
Consent Decree (with Exhibit A—Site
Map).
Henry S. Friedman,
Assistant Section Chief, Environmental
Enforcement Section, Environment and
Natural Resources Division.
[FR Doc. 2012–6066 Filed 3–13–12; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 4410–15–P
DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE
srobinson on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
Notice of Lodging of Second Consent
Decree Under the Clean Air Act
Notice is hereby given that on March
6, 2012, a proposed Second Consent
Decree in United States and the State of
Kansas v. Coffeyville Resources Refining
& Marketing, LLC et. al., 04-cv-01064 (D.
Kan. 2004), was lodged with the United
States Court for the District of Kansas.
On June 13, 2004, the Court entered
a Consent Decree in this action (Docket
No. 8) that required Defendant
Coffeyville Resources Refining &
Marketing, L.L.C. (‘‘CRRM’’) to install
certain air pollution controls to reduce
VerDate Mar<15>2010
19:41 Mar 13, 2012
Jkt 226001
emissions of oxides, sulfur dioxide and
particulate matter at its oil refinery
located in Coffeyville, Kansas. Under
the proposed Second Consent Decree
the United States and State grant CRRM
an extension on installation of some of
these controls. And CRRM has agreed to
implement new and upgraded pollution
controls; to comply with more stringent
emission limits, and to follow more
aggressive leak-detection and repair
practices. These measures will reduce
CRRM’s emission of various nitrogen
oxides (NOx), sulfur dioxide (SO2),
volatile organic compounds, particulate
matter, carbon monoxide, and other
pollutants that affect air quality. CRRM
will also pay approximately $970,000 in
civil penalties under the Clean Air Act,
the Comprehensive Environmental
Response, Compensation, and Liability
Act, and the Emergency Planning and
Community Right-to-Know Act.
The Department of Justice will receive
for a period of thirty (30) days from the
date of this publication comments
relating to the Second Consent Decree.
Comments should be addressed to the
Assistant Attorney General,
Environment and Natural Resources
Division, and either emailed to
pubcomment-ees.enrd@usdoj.gov or
mailed to P.O. Box 7611, U.S.
Department of Justice, Washington, DC
20044–7611, and should refer to United
States and State of Kansas v. Coffeyville
Resources Refining & Marketing, LLC et.
al., 04-cv-01064 (D. Kan. 2004), D.J. Ref.
90–5–1–2–07459/1.
During the public comment period,
the Second Consent Decree may also be
examined on the following Department
of Justice Web site: https://
www.usdoj.gov/enrd/
Consent_Decrees.html. A copy of the
Second Consent Decree may also be
obtained by mail from the Consent
Decree Library, P.O. Box 7611, U.S.
Department of Justice, Washington, DC
20044–7611 or by faxing or emailing a
request to ‘‘Consent Decree Copy’’
(EESCDCopy.ENRD@usdoj.gov), fax no.
(202) 514–0097, phone confirmation
number (202) 514–5271. If requesting a
copy from the Consent Decree Library
by mail, please enclose a check in the
amount of $52.25 (25 cents per page
reproduction cost) payable to the U.S.
Treasury or, if requesting by email or
fax, forward a check in that amount to
the Consent Decree Library at the
address given above.
Robert E. Maher, Jr.,
Assistant Chief, Environmental Enforcement
Section, Environment and Natural Resources
Division.
[FR Doc. 2012–6044 Filed 3–13–12; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 4410–15–P
PO 00000
Frm 00104
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
15125
DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE
Antitrust Division
United States v. Morgan Stanley;
Public Comments and Response on
Proposed Final Judgment
Pursuant to the Antitrust Procedures
and Penalties Act, 15 U.S.C. 16(b)–(h),
the United States hereby publishes
below the comments received on the
proposed Final Judgment in United
States v. Morgan Stanley, Civil Action
No. 1:11–CV–06875–WHP, which were
filed in the United States District Court
for the Southern District of New York on
March 6, 2012, together with the
response of the United States to the
comments.
Copies of the comments and the
response are available for inspection at
the Department of Justice Antitrust
Division, 450 Fifth Street, NW., Suite
1010, Washington, DC 20530
(telephone: 202–514–2481), on the
Department of Justice’s Web site at
https://www.justice.gov/atr, and at the
Office of the Clerk of the United States
District Court for the Southern District
of New York, 500 Pearl Street, New
York, New York 10007. Copies of any of
these materials may be obtained upon
request and payment of a copying fee.
Patricia A. Brink,
Director of Civil Enforcement.
IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT
COURT FOR THE SOUTHERN
DISTRICT OF NEW YORK
UNITED STATES OF AMERICA,
Plaintiff, v. MORGAN STANLEY,
Defendant.
Civil Action No.: 11–civ–6875 WHP
Hon. William Pauley III
RESPONSE OF PLAINTIFF UNITED
STATES TO PUBLIC COMMENTS ON
THE PROPOSED FINAL JUDGMENT
Pursuant to the requirements of the
Antitrust Procedures and Penalties Act,
15 U.S.C. § 16(b)–(h) (‘‘Tunney Act’’),
the United States files the public
comments concerning the proposed
Final Judgment in this case and the
United States’ response to those
comments. After careful consideration,
the United States continues to believe
that the relief sought in the proposed
Final Judgment will provide an effective
and appropriate remedy for the antitrust
violation alleged in the Complaint. The
United States will move the Court for
entry of the proposed Final Judgment
after the public comments and this
Response have been published in the
Federal Register, pursuant to 15 U.S.C.
§ 16(d).
E:\FR\FM\14MRN1.SGM
14MRN1
15126
Federal Register / Vol. 77, No. 50 / Wednesday, March 14, 2012 / Notices
I. PROCEDURAL HISTORY
The United States brought this
lawsuit against Defendant Morgan
Stanley on September 30, 2011, to
remedy a violation of Section 1 of the
Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. § 1. In January
2006, Morgan Stanley Capital Group
Inc. (‘‘MSCG’’), a subsidiary of
defendant Morgan Stanley,1 executed
agreements with KeySpan Corporation
(‘‘KeySpan’’) and Astoria Generating
Company Acquisitions, L.L.C.
(‘‘Astoria’’) that would effectively
combine the economic interests of the
two largest competitors in the New York
City electric capacity market. The likely
effect of this combination was to
increase capacity prices for the retail
electricity suppliers who must purchase
capacity, and, in turn, to increase the
prices consumers pay for electricity.
Simultaneously with the filing of the
Complaint, the United States filed a
proposed Final Judgment and a
Stipulation signed by the United States
and Morgan consenting to the entry of
the proposed Final Judgment after
compliance with the requirements of the
Tunney Act. Pursuant to those
requirements, the United States filed a
Competitive Impact Statement (‘‘CIS’’)
in this Court on September 30, 2011;
published the proposed Final Judgment
and CIS in the Federal Register on
October 11, 2011, see United States v.
Morgan Stanley, Proposed Final
Judgment and Competitive Impact
Statement, 76 Fed. Reg. 62843 (Oct. 11,
2011); and published summaries of the
terms of the proposed Final Judgment
and CIS, together with directions for the
submission of written comments
relating to the proposed Final Judgment
(‘‘PFJ’’), in The Washington Times for
seven days (October 10 through October
14 and October 17 and 18, 2011) and in
The New York Post for seven days
(October 25 through October 31, 2011).
The 60-day period for public comments
ended on December 30, 2011. The
United States received two comments,
as described below, which are attached
hereto.
II. THE COMPLAINT AND THE
PROPOSED FINAL JUDGMENT
srobinson on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
A. Background
As alleged in the Complaint and as
discussed more fully in the CIS [Dkt. #2]
at 2–7, this case involves Morgan’s
participation in an agreement with
KeySpan that caused an anticompetitive
1 MSCG and Morgan Stanley are collectively
referred to hereinafter as ‘‘Morgan.’’
VerDate Mar<15>2010
19:41 Mar 13, 2012
Jkt 226001
effect in the New York City Capacity
Market.2
In 2005, KeySpan, a pivotal capacity
supplier, anticipated that tight supply
and demand conditions in the New
York City capacity market would ease
due to entry of new generation.
Concerned that market entry would lead
to lower prices and revenues, KeySpan
studied various options, including the
direct purchase of Astoria. Such an
acquisition, however, would have raised
significant market power concerns.
KeySpan decided instead to approach
Morgan to arrange a financial
transaction that would provide KeySpan
an indirect financial interest in Astoria’s
capacity sales. Morgan informed
KeySpan that such an agreement
between Morgan and KeySpan would be
contingent on Morgan also entering into
an agreement with Astoria, the only
other generator with sufficient capacity
to offset Morgan’s payments to
KeySpan.
In January 2006, Morgan entered into
a financial derivative agreement with
KeySpan (the ‘‘Morgan/KeySpan
Swap’’), and, at the same time, an
offsetting agreement with Astoria (the
‘‘Morgan/Astoria Hedge’’). Under the
terms of the Morgan/KeySpan Swap,
when the market clearing price for
capacity was above a certain amount,
Morgan essentially was required to pay
KeySpan a multiple of the difference
between the clearing price and the strike
price.3 The terms of both the Morgan/
KeySpan Swap and the Morgan/Astoria
Hedge ran from May 2006 through April
2009. Morgan earned approximately
$21.6 million in net revenues from the
two agreements.
The revenues from Astoria’s capacity
sales that KeySpan obtained through the
Morgan/KeySpan Swap effectively
eliminated KeySpan’s incentive to
compete for sales in the same way a
purchase of Astoria or a direct
agreement between KeySpan and
Astoria would have done. As a result,
KeySpan consistently bid its capacity
into the capacity auctions at the highest
allowed price and, despite the addition
of significant new generating capacity in
2 In the state of New York, sellers of retail
electricity must purchase a product from generators
known as installed capacity (‘‘capacity’’).
3 Under the Morgan/KeySpan Swap, if the market
price for capacity was above the strike price ($7.57
per kW-month), Morgan would pay KeySpan the
difference between the market price and $7.57
times 1800 MW; if the market price was below
$7.57, KeySpan would pay Morgan the difference
times 1800 MW. Under the Morgan/Astoria Hedge,
if the market price for capacity was above $7.07 per
kW-month, Astoria would pay Morgan the
difference times 1800 MW; if the market price was
below $7.07, Astoria would be paid the difference
times 1800 MW. Morgan retained the differential
(e.g., $7.57–$7.07 times 1800 MW) as revenues.
PO 00000
Frm 00105
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
New York City, the market price of
capacity did not decline.4 This result
would not have been achieved without
Morgan’s participation.
B. United States v. KeySpan
On February 22, 2010, the United
States filed suit against KeySpan for its
role in the Morgan/KeySpan Swap.
Simultaneous with the filing of its
Complaint, the United States filed a
proposed Final Judgment requiring
KeySpan to pay to the United States $12
million as disgorgement of ill-gotten
gains. See Complaint, United States v.
KeySpan Corp., No. 10–1415 (S.D.N.Y.
Feb. 22, 2010). On February 2, 2011,
after completion of the Tunney Act
procedures, the Court entered the
KeySpan Final Judgment, and, in
making its public interest
determination, found that disgorgement
is available to remedy violations of the
Sherman Act. See United States v.
KeySpan Corp., 763 F. Supp. 2d 633,
638–41 (S.D.N.Y. 2011) (WHP).
C. The Morgan Complaint and Proposed
Final Judgment
On September 30, 2011, the United
States filed the current suit against
Morgan for its role in the Morgan/
KeySpan Swap. The United States
alleges that Morgan entered into an
agreement (the Morgan/KeySpan Swap),
the likely effect of which was to
increase prices in the New York City
Capacity Market, in violation of Section
1 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. § 1.
Simultaneous with the filing of its
Complaint, the United States filed a
proposed Final Judgment requiring
Morgan to pay to the Treasury of the
United States $4.8 million as
disgorgement of ill-gotten gains. The
proposed Final Judgment requires
Morgan to disgorge profits gained as a
result of its unlawful agreement in
restraint of trade. As stated in the CIS,
the proposed relief serves the public
interest by depriving Morgan of illgotten gains, thereby deterring Morgan
and others from engaging in similar
anticompetitive conduct in the future.
4 The effects of the Morgan/KeySpan Swap
continued until March 2008, at which time changes
in regulatory conditions eliminated KeySpan’s
ability to affect the market price. KeySpan was sold
to another company in August 2007. The State of
New York conditioned its approval of the
acquisition on the divestiture of KeySpan’s
Ravenswood generating assets and required
KeySpan to bid its New York capacity at zero from
March 2008 until the divestiture was completed.
Since then, the market price for capacity has
declined.
E:\FR\FM\14MRN1.SGM
14MRN1
srobinson on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
Federal Register / Vol. 77, No. 50 / Wednesday, March 14, 2012 / Notices
II. STANDARDS GOVERNING THE
COURT’S PUBLIC INTEREST
DETERMINATION UNDER THE
TUNNEY ACT
The Tunney Act calls for the Court, in
making its public interest
determination, to consider certain
factors relating to the competitive
impact of the judgment and whether it
adequately remedies the harm alleged in
the complaint. See 15 U.S.C.
§ 16(e)(1)(A) and (B) (listing factors to be
considered).
This public interest inquiry is
necessarily a limited one, as the United
States is entitled to deference in crafting
its antitrust settlements, especially with
respect to the scope of its complaint and
the adequacy of its remedy. See
generally United States v. Microsoft
Corp., 56 F.3d 1448, 1458–62 (DC Cir.
1995); United States v. SBC Commc’ns,
489 F. Supp. 2d 1, 12–17 (D.D.C. 2007).
Under the Tunney Act, the ‘‘Court’s
function is not to determine whether the
proposed [d]ecree results in the balance
of rights and liabilities that is the one
that will best serve society, but only to
ensure that the resulting settlement is
within the reaches of the public
interest.’’ KeySpan, 763 F. Supp. 2d at
637 (quoting United States v. Alex
Brown & Sons, 963 F. Supp. 235, 238
(S.D.N.Y. 1997) (quoting Microsoft, 56
F.3d at 1460) (emphasis in original),
aff’d sub nom, United States v. Bleznak,
153 F.3d 16 (2d Cir. 1998)).
With respect to the scope of the
complaint, the Tunney Act review does
not provide for an examination of
possible competitive harms the United
States did not allege. See, e.g.,
Microsoft, 56 F.3d at 1459 (holding that
it is improper to reach beyond the
complaint to evaluate claims that the
government did not make).
With respect to the sufficiency of the
proposed remedy, the United States is
entitled to deference as to its views of
the nature of the case, its perception of
the market structure, and its predictions
as to the effect of proposed remedies.
See, e.g., KeySpan, 763 F. Supp. 2d at
642; SBC Commc’ns, 489 F. Supp. 2d at
17 (holding that the United States is
entitled to deference as to predictions
about the efficacy of its remedies).
Under this standard, the United States
need not show that a settlement will
perfectly remedy the alleged antitrust
harm; rather, it need only provide a
factual basis for concluding that the
settlement is a reasonably adequate
remedy for the alleged harm. SBC
Commc’ns, 489 F. Supp. 2d at 17. A
court should not reject the United
States’ proposed remedies merely
because other remedies may be
VerDate Mar<15>2010
19:41 Mar 13, 2012
Jkt 226001
preferable. KeySpan, 763 F. Supp. 2d at
637–38.
III. SUMMARY OF COMMENTS
The United States received formal
comments from the Public Service
Commission of the State of New York
(‘‘PSC’’) and from AARP, a nonprofit
organization that helps people over the
age of fifty.5 At the outset, both
comments commend the United States
for enforcing the antitrust laws to
protect the integrity of New York
capacity markets.
The comments raise three central
objections: (1) that the proposed $4.8
million dollar disgorgement is
inadequate to deter similar
anticompetitive conduct or otherwise
serve its remedial purpose, especially
given the likely magnitude of the injury
to consumers from any increase in New
York City capacity prices (PSC Cmts at
7–14; AARP Cmts at 11–16 and 19–25);
(2) that the decree does not contain an
admission of wrongdoing by Morgan
(AARP Cmts at 16–18); and (3) that the
disgorged proceeds, rather than being
remitted to the Treasury, should directly
or indirectly benefit electricity
consumers who paid higher electricity
rates as a result of the illegal agreement
(AARP Cmts at 10–16).
AARP recommends that the United
States withdraw from the proposed
settlement and proceed in the litigation
or renegotiate a settlement with Morgan
that would provide equitable relief to
electric utility customers, an admission
by Morgan of its violation of the
Sherman Act, a quantification of the
total harm to consumers, and a
disgorgement of all profits Morgan
realized from the transaction at issue.
AARP Cmts at 28. The PSC asks the
Court to order the United States to
supplement the record. PSC Cmts at 16.
IV. RESPONSE TO THE COMMENTS
The United States has carefully
considered these objections but finds
that they do not warrant modification of
the proposed Final Judgment.
A. The Proposed Remedy Is Appropriate
and Deters Anticompetitive Conduct
The commenters argue that
disgorgement of $4.8 million is an
inadequate remedy that will not serve as
an effective deterrent, especially when
5 On January 13, 2012, State Senator Michael
Gianaris and New York City Council Member Peter
Vallone sent a joint letter to the Court asking the
Court to re-evaluate the proposed settlement. The
letter was placed in the case docket [Dkt. #9]. The
letter raises issues similar to those raised by the
PSC and AARP; accordingly, these issues will be
fully addressed in this response of the United States
to the formal comments submitted by the PSC and
AARP.
PO 00000
Frm 00106
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
15127
compared to Morgan’s approximately
$21.6 million net revenues earned under
the Swap and the increased prices paid
by electricity consumers. Such concerns
are misplaced.6
The proposed remedy constitutes
significant and meaningful relief. In its
action against KeySpan, the United
States sought disgorgement under the
Sherman Act for the first time. In
approving that settlement, this Court
recognized that the disgorgement by a
power generator engaged in an alleged
anticompetitive scheme would become
‘‘an important marker for enforcement
agencies and utility regulators alike.’’
KeySpan, 763 F. Supp. 2d at 642. In this
case, the United States seeks
disgorgement from the financial services
firm that facilitated the transaction. Just
as the KeySpan remedy created an
important marker for disgorgement from
the principal competitor in an
anticompetitive scheme, the proposed
remedy in this unprecedented case
demonstrates the United States’ resolve
to pursue financial services firms that
leverage derivative agreements for
anticompetitive ends, and the antitrust
liability that may result from such
enforcement actions. Financial services
firms contemplating the use of such
anticompetitive agreements will now
recognize the prospect of Sherman Act
liability and disgorgement, thereby
diminishing their appetite for and
deterring this illegal conduct. Indeed,
the filing of the proposed settlement has
already prompted legal commentators to
warn about the enforcement issues
raised by this case, including the duty
of financial services firms to consider
the implications of their agreements on
competition in the underlying markets.7
6 AARP requests access to the derivative
agreements. AARP Cmts at 21. The agreement that
the United States alleged violated the Sherman
Act—the Morgan/KeySpan Swap—is publicly
available as an attachment to KeySpan’s January 18,
2006 Form 8–K filing with the SEC in which
KeySpan announced that it had entered into the
transaction, available at https://www.sec.gov/
Archivesiedgar/data/10623791000106
237906000004/ex101-8kjan2406.txt.
7 See, e.g., Mary Arm Mason & William Monts III,
Morgan Stanley to Disgorge Profits Earned from
Anticompetitive Derivative Agreements, Hogan
Lovells (Dec. 9, 2011) (reporting that ‘‘[Ole key
points from the Morgan Stanley case for financial
services clients are: (1) the DOJ is prepared to use
Section 1 to outlaw financial arrangements aimed
at producing anticompetitive effects, (2) the DOJ
will take enforcement action against the financial
services companies that facilitate these
arrangements, even though they do not participate
in the underlying physical commodity market, and
(3) pure financial players may have a duty to
examine the competitive effects of their
arrangements on the underlying markets’’),
available at https://emailcc.com/rv/ff000213
bdac60e42b089aa3f84a8b12fdc2a196; Barry Nigro
& Maria Cirincione, DOJ Orders Financial Services
E:\FR\FM\14MRN1.SGM
Continued
14MRN1
15128
Federal Register / Vol. 77, No. 50 / Wednesday, March 14, 2012 / Notices
srobinson on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
The PSC and AARP nevertheless
argue that disgorgement of anything
short of the $21.6 million in net
revenues earned by Morgan under the
Swap 8 will not strip Morgan of the
entirety of its ill-gotten gains and
therefore will not deter the conduct at
issue. This position ignores the
deterrent value of the proposed
settlement described above. It also
ignores the disputes that would likely
arise in calculating Morgan’s ill-gotten
gains for the purpose of determining
disgorgement. The theory of the United
States’ case rests on the illegality of the
Morgan/KeySpan Swap but not the
Astoria Hedge. As such, were this
matter to proceed to trial, Morgan would
likely contend that but for the Morgan/
KeySpan Swap, it would have entered
into a legitimate transaction with
someone other than KeySpan to offset
the Astoria Hedge, and that any
disgorgement remedy should be
adjusted downward to account for a
legitimate retum.9 Although the United
States would have contested these
arguments and sought disgorgement of
the full $21.6 million in net revenues
had this action proceeded to trial, the
settlement reflects, among other things,
the fact that there is a dispute about the
amount of Morgan’s net revenues that
were ill-gotten.
The United States recognizes that it
has not proved its case at trial and that
‘‘a court considering a proposed
settlement does not have actual findings
that the defendant[] engaged in illegal
practices, as would exist after a trial.’’
SBC Commc’ns, 489 F. Supp. 2d at 15
(citing Microsoft, 56 F.3d at 1461). The
$4.8 million disgorgement amount is the
product of settlement negotiations and
accounts for litigation risks and costs. It
is appropriate to consider litigation risk
and the context of a settlement when
evaluating whether a proposed remedy
Firm to Disgorge Profits from Derivative Contract,
Fried Frank Antitrust & Comp. L. (Oct. 17, 2011)
(reporting that this case ‘‘puts firms on notice that
any type of agreement facilitating anticompetitive
conduct is subject to scrutiny and that the DOJ may
seek penalties against indirect third party
participants, as well as direct competitors’’),
available at https://www.friedfrank.com/siteFiles/
Publications/Final%2010-17-11%20D0J
%200rders%20Financial%20Services%20Firm%20
to%20Disgorge%20Profits%
20from%20Derivative%20Contract.pdf.
8 There is no dispute that Morgan earned $21.6
million under the two derivative agreements.
9 Though a legitimate off-setting counter-party
would likely not have agreed to the strike price as
high as the $7.57 per kW-month found in the
Morgan/KeySpan Swap, Morgan would nonetheless
have earned revenues from a legitimate off-setting
transaction so long as it exceeded the $7.07 per KWmonth price in the Astoria Hedge. In the alternative,
Morgan would also dispute that the entire $21.6
million earned under both agreements is cognizable
as ill-gotten gains. See CIS at note 4.
VerDate Mar<15>2010
19:41 Mar 13, 2012
Jkt 226001
is in the public interest.10 As this Court
has recognized ‘‘Mlle adequacy of the
disgorgement amount must be evaluated
in view of the Government’s decision to
settle its claims and seek entry of the
consent decree. When a litigant chooses
to forgo discovery and trial in favor of
settlement, full damages cannot be
expected.’’ 11
Here, the litigation costs and risks are
not insignificant. The United States
would have had to establish at trial that
the KeySpan Swap caused
anticompetitive effects in the New York
capacity market, a complex endeavor
that would have required substantial
fact and expert testimony and evidence.
And, in the present case against Morgan
Stanley, the United States would have
had the additional burden of
establishing the liability of a financial
services firm for using a derivative
agreement to facilitate an
anticompetitive effect even though the
company itself was not a participant in
the underlying market. Assuming the
United States prevailed on liability,
there would be additional risk, as
discussed above, in establishing the
proper disgorgement amount. While the
United States is confident that it could
prevail on these issues at trial, the
settlement obviates the risk—and
significant cost—of litigation.
The PSC and AARP also argue that
the reasonableness of the proposed
remedy should be evaluated in light of
the ratepayer harm caused by Morgan.
PSC Cmts at 13–15; AARP Cmts at 5, 11,
16. In essence, they seek a disgorgement
amount that takes into account the
losses suffered by retail electricity
consumers. As this Court recognized in
KeySpan, such comments ‘‘fail to
comprehend the nature of the
disgorgement remedy. The ’primary
purpose of disgorgement is not to
compensate investors,’ but rather to
divest a wrongdoer of the proceeds of
their misconduct.’’ KeySpan, 763 F.
Supp. 2d at 642 (quoting SEC v.
Cavanaugh, 445 F. 3d 105, 117 (2d Cir.
2006)). Indeed, the extent of market
harm is not relevant to the disgorgement
calculation; once a violation has been
established, a district court ‘‘possesses
the equitable power to grant
disgorgement without inquiring
10 Indeed, ‘‘room must be made for the
government to grant concessions in the negotiation
process for settlements.’’ SBC, 489 F. Supp. 2d at
15.
11 KeySpan, 763 F. Supp. 2d at 642 (citing In re
Linerboard Antitrust Litig., 321 F. Supp. 2d 619,
633 (E.D. Pa 2004) (collecting cases) & In re Milken
& Assocs. Sec Litig., 150 F.R.D. 46, 54 (S.D.N.Y
1993) (‘‘The Second Circuit has held that a
settlement can be approved even though the
benefits amount to a small percentage of the
recovery sought.’’)).
PO 00000
Frm 00107
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
whether, or to what extent, identifiable
private parties have been damaged by
[the violation].’’ 12
In this case, the source of Morgan’s
ill-gotten gains is the revenues it earned
under the derivative agreements.
Indeed, the derivative agreements
represent Morgan’s only source of
revenue in this case. Morgan did not
participate in the actual capacity market
and thus it did not earn any auction
revenues, much less pocket consumer
overpayments. Moreover, as the United
States explained in the KeySpan
proceedings,13 an inquiry into consumer
harm would require the Court to assess
the price of capacity that would have
prevailed absent the Swap, a
problematic exercise given the
uncertainty of determining market
outcomes absent the Swap. Accordingly,
given the difficulty of definitively
estimating the harm to the market and
its irrelevance to the questions relating
to the adequacy of the disgorgement
remedy, AARP’s assertion that the
United States is obligated to provide
estimates of total economic harm and
profits received by all market
participants resulting from the alleged
violation should be rejected.
B. Public Policy Rejects the Contention
That a Settlement of a Government
Antitrust Case Should Contain an
Admission of Wrongdoing
AARP argues that the proposed final
judgment is not in the public interest
because it does not contain an
admission or finding that Morgan
violated the law. Similarly, the PSC
quotes language from SEC v. Citigroup
challenging the sufficiency of a consent
judgment ‘‘that does not involve any
admissions’’ by the defendant.14
Government antitrust suits are
governed by a specialized statutory
regime that provides no basis to require
that consent decrees include either a
finding or an admission of liability.15
Congress has designed the remedial
12 SEC v. Blavin, 760 F.2d 706, 713 (6th Cir.
1985). See also SEC v. Tome, 833 F.2d 1086, 1096
(2d Cir. 1987) (‘‘Whether or not [any victims] may
be entitled to money damages is immaterial [to
disgorgement].’’).
13 See October 12, 2010 Transcript of Hearing in
United States v. KeySpan, 1:10-cv-01415–WHP, at
10–14. In addition, in this case as in KeySpan,
commenters’ estimates of consumer harm may be
significantly overstated. Id. at 14–15.
14 AARP Cmts at 16–18 & 28 (recommending that
the PFJ be amended to include an ‘‘admission by
Morgan of its violation’’); PSC Cmts at 10 (quoting
SEC v. Citigroup Global Markets, Inc., Slip Op. at
10, 2011 WL 5903733 at *5 (S.D.N.Y. 2011)).
15 The district court proceedings in the Citigroup
case have been temporarily stayed by the Court of
Appeals (pending a panel ruling on a motion to stay
pending appeal). SEC v. Citigroup Global Markets
Inc., 2011 WL 6937373 (2nd Cir. Dec. 27, 2011).
E:\FR\FM\14MRN1.SGM
14MRN1
srobinson on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
Federal Register / Vol. 77, No. 50 / Wednesday, March 14, 2012 / Notices
provisions of the antitrust laws to
encourage consent judgments, which
allow the government to obtain relief
without the ‘‘time, expense and
inevitable risk of litigation.’’ United
States v. Armour and Co., 402 U.S. 673,
681 (1971). Thus, for nearly a century,
the antitrust laws have expressly limited
the ability of private plaintiffs seeking
treble damages to rely on consent
decrees entered in government cases.
Section 5 of the Clayton Act, originally
enacted in 1914,16 provides that
litigated final judgments establishing a
violation in civil or criminal cases
‘‘brought by or on behalf of the United
States under the antitrust laws’’ shall be
‘‘prima facie evidence’’ against the
defendant in subsequent private
litigation, but the statute specifies that
this provision does not apply to
‘‘consent judgments or decrees entered
before any testimony has been taken.’’
15 U.S.C. § 16(a). Under this regime, a
defendant can elect to accept a consent
decree and avoid the risk of a litigated
judgment that would seriously weaken
its position in follow-on private
litigation. Congress provided this
exception to the Clayton Act’s prima
facie evidence provision ‘‘in order to
encourage defendants to settle promptly
government-initiated antitrust claims
and thereby to save the government the
time and expense of further litigation.’’
United States v. National Ass’n of
Broadcasters, 553 F. Supp. 621, 623
(D.D.C. 1982) (collecting cases).
Requiring admissions or findings of
liability as a prerequisite to entering a
consent decree would undercut
Congress’s purpose and contravene the
public interest in allowing the
government to obtain relief without the
risk and delay of litigation.
Congress confirmed its continuing
recognition of the importance of consent
decrees when it amended the Clayton
Act in 1974 to specify procedural
requirements governing a district court’s
determination of whether entry of a
proposed consent decree in a
government antitrust case is in the
public interest. Antitrust Procedures
and Penalties Act, § 2, Pub. L. No. 93–
528, 88 Stat 1706 (1974), codified at 15
U.S.C. § 16(b)–(h) (‘‘Tunney Act’’). The
repeated references to the ‘‘alleged’’
violation in the language of the Tunney
Act strongly suggest that Congress did
not expect decrees arising under the
antitrust laws to contain admissions of
liability.17 And the legislative history
16 63 Cong. Ch. 323, 38 Stat. 730, 731, codified
as amended at 15 U.S.C. § 16(a).
17 With one exception, every reference to
‘‘violation’’ or ‘‘violations’’ in the Tunney Act is
immediately preceded by ‘‘alleged.’’ The only
VerDate Mar<15>2010
19:41 Mar 13, 2012
Jkt 226001
15129
unambiguously demonstrates Congress’
understanding that government antitrust
settlements typically occur without an
admission or finding of liability. The
Senate Report accompanying S. 782, the
bill that became the Tunney Act,
explains:
The entry of a consent decree is a
judicial act which requires the approval
of a United States district court. Once
entered the consent decree represents a
contract between the government and
the respondent upon which the parties
agree to terminate the litigation.
Pursuant to the terms of the decree, the
defendant agrees to abide by certain
conditions in the future. However the
defendant does not admit to having
violated the law as alleged in the
complaint. Obviously, the consent
decree is of crucial importance as an
enforcement tool, since it permits the
allocation of resources elsewhere.18
The corresponding House Report is
equally clear on the point: ‘‘Ordinarily,
defendants do not admit to having
violated the antitrust or other laws
alleged as violated in complaints that
are settled.’’ 19 Moreover, both reports
plainly reveal that Congress not only
understood the practice of entering into
such consent decrees, but encouraged it,
considering them a ‘‘legitimate and
integral part of antitrust enforcement’’
and urging that they be retained ‘‘as a
substantial antitrust enforcement
tool.’’ 20
Accordingly, the government
routinely enters into antitrust consent
decrees explicitly disclaiming
admissions or findings of liability.21
The Supreme Court has long endorsed
the entry of consent judgments in which
there is no finding of liability,22 and it
has done so even when the defendant
has affirmatively denied the alleged
violation.23
Following enactment of the Tunney
Act, courts have expressly recognized
the Congressional intent to preserve the
policy of encouraging antitrust consent
decree expressed in that legislation.24
Only once, to our knowledge, has a
district court objected to a proposed
consent decree on the basis that a
defendant had not admitted liability or
wrongdoing, but this objection was
specifically rejected on appeal. In
United States v. Microsoft, the district
court refused to enter the proposed
consent decree in part because the
defendant denied ‘‘that the conduct
charged in the Government’s complaint
to which it has consented, violates the
antitrust laws.’’ 25 The DC Circuit
reversed, expressly holding
‘‘unjustified’’ the district court’s
criticism of the defendant ‘‘for declining
to admit that the practices charged in
the complaint actually violated the
antitrust laws.’’ 26 The Court of Appeals
emphasized that the ‘‘important
question is whether [the defendant] will
abide by the terms of the consent decree
regardless of whether it is willing to
admit wrongdoing.’’ 27 We are aware of
no government antitrust case in which
a court refused to enter a consent decree
because a defendant had failed to admit
liability.
AARP’s contention that absent an
admission of wrongdoing or an
exception is a reference to ‘‘the violations set forth
in the complaint.’’ 15 U.S.C. § 16(e)(2) as enacted,
currently 16 U.S.C. § 16(e)(1)(B). The Tunney Act
contains no reference to admissions or findings of
violations or of liability. Congress amended the
Tunney Act in 2004, but those amendments do not
affect the analysis here.
18 S. Rep. No. 298, 93d Cong., 1st Sess. (1973) (‘‘S.
Rep.’’) at 5 (emphasis added). See also 119 Cong.
Rec. 3449, 3451 (Feb. 6, 1973 floor statement of
Senator Tunney: ‘‘Essentially the decree is a device
by which the defendant, while refusing to admit
guilt, agrees to modify its conduct and in some
cases to accept certain remedies designed to correct
the violation asserted by the Government.’’). (The
legislative history of the Tunney Act, including the
House and Senate Reports and the statement of
Senator Tunney cited herein, is available at
https://www.justice.gov/jmd/ls/legislative_histories/
pl93-528/pl93-528.html).
19 H. Rep. No. 1463, 93rd Cong., 2d Sess. (1974)
(‘‘H. Rep.’’) at 6, reprinted at 1974 U.S. Code Cong.
& Admin. News 6535, 6536–37. See also id.
(‘‘Present law, 15 U.S.C. § 16(a), encourages
settlement by consent decree as part of the legal
policies expressed in the antitrust laws. * * * The
bill preserves these legal and enforcement policies.
* * *’’).
20 S. Rep. at 3 & 7; see also H. Rep. at 8, 1974
U.S.C.C.A.N. at 6539 (also describing consent
decrees as a ‘‘viable settlement option’’).
21 The proposed Final Judgment in this case states
that the United States and defendant Morgan have
‘‘consented to the entry of this Final Judgment
without trial or adjudication of any issue of fact or
law, for settlement purposes only, and without this
Final Judgment constituting any evidence against or
an admission by Morgan for any purpose with
respect to any claim or allegation contained in the
Complaint.’’ PFJ at 1. Equivalent statements are
conventional in government antitrust consent
decrees negotiated pre-trial.
22 Cf: Armour, 402 U.S. at 681 (interpreting
consent decree in which defendants had denied
liability for the allegations raised in the complaint);
see also 18A Wright and Miller, Federal Practice
and Procedure § 4443, at 256–57 (2d ed. 2002)
(‘‘central characteristic of a consent judgment is that
the court has not actually resolved the substance of
the issues presented’’).
23 See Swift & Co. v. United States, 276 U.S. 311,
327 (1928) (refusing to vacate injunctive relief in
consent judgment that contained recitals in which
defendants asserted their innocence).
24 E.g., United States v. Alex. Brown & Sons, Inc.,
963 F. Supp. 235, 238–39 (S.D.N.Y. 1997) (‘‘In
enacting the Tunney Act, Congress recognized the
high rate of settlement in public antitrust cases and
wished to encourage settlement by consent decrees
as part of the legal policies expressed in the
antitrust laws.’’) (internal quotations omitted).
25 United States v. Microsoft, 159 F.R.D. 318, 337
(D.D.C. 1995), rev ’d 56 F.3d 1448 (D.C. Cir. 1995).
26 United States v. Microsoft, 56 F.3d at 1448,
1461 (D.C. Cir. 1995).
27 Id.
PO 00000
Frm 00108
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
E:\FR\FM\14MRN1.SGM
14MRN1
15130
Federal Register / Vol. 77, No. 50 / Wednesday, March 14, 2012 / Notices
srobinson on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
adjudication of the facts entry of the
decree would not be in the public
interest is unwarranted. The relief that
would be afforded by the proposed
decree is appropriate to the violation
alleged. The Tunney Act and the public
interest require no more. To insist on
more is to impose substantial resource
costs on government antitrust
enforcement; to risk the possibility of
litigation resulting in no relief at all; to
contravene a century of congressional
and judicial policy; and to establish a
precedent that could impede
enforcement of the antitrust laws in the
future.
C. Disgorgement of Proceeds to the U.S.
Treasury Is Appropriate
AARP argues that Morgan’s $4.8
million disgorgement payment should
be made to entities other than the U.S.
Treasury in order to benefit the
electricity customers in New York City
who paid higher prices as a result of
Morgan’s conduct. The United States
shares AARP’s concern for the New
York City ratepayers and, indeed,
brought this case and sought
disgorgement in order to deter financial
services firms from entering into
financial arrangements that cause
anticompetitive effects. The United
States has carefully considered the
suggested alternative uses for the
disgorgement proceeds but has
determined that payment to the U.S.
Treasury is the most appropriate result
in this circumstance.
The alternative distribution plan
proposed by AARP seeks, in effect, to
restore funds to ratepayers. As this
Court recognized in KeySpan, 763 F.
Supp. 2d at 643. A remedy that seeks to
reimburse funds to New York City
ratepayers would raise questions
relating to the filed rate doctrine, which
bars remedies (such as damages) that
result, in effect, in payment by
customers and receipt by sellers of a rate
different from that on file for the
regulated service. See generally Square
D Co. v. Niagara Frontier, 476 U.S. 409,
423 (1986). Indeed, a lawsuit filed by
private plaintiffs seeking damages from
KeySpan and Morgan based on the
Swap has been dismissed on the ground
that the action is barred as a matter of
law under the filed rate doctrine.28
In this case, the United States
specifically chose to seek disgorgement,
rather than restitution, as a remedy for
this violation. As discussed in the CIS,
disgorgement is particularly appropriate
28 See Simon v. KeySpan, 785 F. Supp. 2d at 138–
39 (dismissing actions based on filed rate doctrine
and other grounds). Plaintiffs have appealed this
decision to the Second Circuit, but a decision has
not yet been rendered.
VerDate Mar<15>2010
19:41 Mar 13, 2012
Jkt 226001
on the facts of this case to fulfill the
remedial goals of the Sherman Act. CIS
at 9–10. Disgorgement also provides
finality, certainty, avoidance of
transaction costs, and potential to do the
most good for the most people. As in
KeySpan, the proposed remedy here is
well within the reaches of the public
interest.29
VI. CONCLUSION
After careful consideration of the
public comments, the United States
remains of the view that the proposed
Final Judgment provides an effective
and appropriate remedy for the antitrust
violation alleged in the Complaint and
that its entry would therefore be in the
public interest.
The United States is submitting this
Response and the public comments to
the Federal Register for publication
pursuant to 15 U.S.C. § 16(d). After
publication occurs, the United States
will move this Court to enter the
proposed Final Judgment.
Dated: March 6, 2012
Respectfully submitted, /s/ Jade Alice
Eaton, jade.eaton@usdoj.gov, Trial
Attorney, U.S. Department of Justice,
Antitrust Division, Transportation,
Energy & Agriculture Section, 450 Fifth
Street, NW, Suite 8000, Washington, DC
20004, Telephone: (202) 307–6316,
Facsimile: (202) 307–2784.
AARP COMMENTS IN OPPOSITION
TO PROPOSED SETTLEMENT AND IN
SUPPORT OF FURTHER
PROCEEDINGS
Preliminary Statement
On September 30, 2011, the United
States Department of Justice Antitrust
Division (‘‘DOT’’) filed a Complaint
commencing this civil antitrust action
against defendant Morgan Stanley. On
the same day, DOJ filed a proposed
Final Judgment, agreed to by Morgan
Stanley, which would settle the case
subject to court review and approval,
along with a Competition Impact
Statement (‘‘CIS’’) in support of the
proposed settlement.1 A notice inviting
public comment 2 on the proposed
29 KeySpan, 763 F. Supp. 2d at 643. Moreover, the
Miscellaneous Receipts Act (‘‘MRA’’) provides that
members of the Executive Branch (including
employees of the Department of Justice) who
receive money for the United States are to remit
such funds directly to the Treasury. 31 U.S.C.
§ 3302(b) (2006). A purpose of the statute is to
protect Congress’ appropriations authority by
ensuring that money collected from various sources
cannot be used for programs not authorized by law.
The proposed remedy avoids any issues of
compliance with the MRA.
1 The court papers are available at https://
www.justice.gov/atr/cases/morgan.html.
2 76 Federal Register, No. 196 (Tuesday, October
11, 2011).
PO 00000
Frm 00109
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
settlement of this action has been
issued, as is required by the Tunney
Act.3 AARP submits these comments to
DOJ in response to the notice.
AARP is a nonpartisan, nonprofit
organization that helps people over the
age of 50 to exercise independence,
choice, and control in ways beneficial to
them and to society as a whole.4 AARP
has millions of members, including
more than 2,500,000 members who
reside in New York state. AARP is
greatly concerned about the threats to
health and safety of vulnerable citizens
caused by New York’s high electricity
costs.5 Because the cost of utilities has
skyrocketed, many low and middleincome families and older people must
now choose between paying utility bills
and paying for other essentials such as
food and medicine. AARP works to
protect consumers from excessive utility
rates and charges.
Many AARP members were adversely
affected by the antitrust violations
alleged in this action, which artificially
increased prices in the electric capacity
markets of the New York Independent
System Operator (‘‘NYISO’’). Although
the excessive charges were paid in the
first instance by load-serving utilities
such as Con Edison, they were directly
passed on to utility customers. Utility
customers had no way to escape
payment of the inflated charges when
their monthly electric bills were
adjusted to include the costs.6
As consumers, AARP members
depend upon the protection of the
antitrust laws against the unlawful
exercise of monopoly or market power,
such as occurred in this case. They must
also rely upon the vigorous enforcement
of the antitrust laws by DOJ and the
courts.
AARP commends DOJ for challenging
Morgan Stanley’s use of financial
derivatives to facilitate gaming by
3 The Antitrust Procedures and Penalties Act (the
‘‘Tunney Act’’), 15 U.S.C. § 16(e)–(f), requires an
opportunity for public comment prior to a court’s
review of any proposed settlement between the
government and an alleged antitrust law violator.
4 For more information about AARP see https://
www.aarp.org/.
5 New York residential electric rates are the
highest in the continental United States. Energy
Information Agency, Electric Power Monthly for
August, 2011, Average Retail Price of Electricity to
Ultimate Customers by End-Use Sector, by State,
table 5.6.A, (Nov. 2011). Available at https://
www.eia.gov/electricity/monthly/index.cfm.
6 ‘‘Every Con Ed customer in the five boroughs
overpaid an average total of at least $40 over two
years during a price-fixing scheme set up by the
owners of a giant Queens power plant, the feds
charge in a court case that would let the alleged
gougers get away with most of the gains.’’ Bill
Sanderson, $157 M Power Abuse, N.Y. Post, March
9, 2010, available at https://www.nypost.com/f/print/
news/local/
power_abuse_SgLN9psbhjopRMEGU68fgK.
E:\FR\FM\14MRN1.SGM
14MRN1
Federal Register / Vol. 77, No. 50 / Wednesday, March 14, 2012 / Notices
Keyspan and Astoria in the NYISO
electricity auctions. AARP urges,
however, that the proposed settlement
be withdrawn and revised, and that
further proceedings be held.
The Complaint and the Proposed
Settlement
srobinson on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
The Complaint alleges that Morgan
Stanley violated Section 1 of the
Sherman Act 7 by entering into separate
financial derivative contracts with two
major competing sellers in the NYISO
electric capacity market, effectively
combining their economic interests. The
Morgan Stanley derivatives reduced the
utilities’ risk of bidding strategically to
raise the clearing price in the NYISO
market, which is paid to all sellers. As
a consequence, higher prices were paid
for capacity by retail utilities, and the
costs were passed through to
consumers.
Under Morgan Stanley’s derivative
contract with the largest seller in the
relevant market, Keyspan Corporation
(‘‘Keyspan’’), Morgan Stanley paid
Keyspan whenever NYISO auction
prices exceeded a fixed level ($7.57/
MW). This rewarded Keyspan when it
set the NYISO clearing price at the
maximum. Even if all of its capacity was
not sold at its high price, Keyspan was
assured of benefitting from it through
the derivative contract. Under Morgan
Stanley’s parallel derivative contract
with Astoria, Morgan Stanley
guaranteed Astoria a fixed floor price for
all its capacity sales, regardless of the
prices established in the NYISO
auctions, and Astoria agreed to pay
Morgan Stanley whenever the NYISO
auction price exceeded the floor price in
the derivative contract. Morgan Stanley
could take profits reaped by Astoria due
to the artificially high price, and give
them to Keyspan. The derivatives thus
worked to insure Keyspan against lost
profits if it lost some sales by bidding
high, at the market rate cap. They
assured Astoria that it would receive a
known fixed price for all of its capacity,
regardless of the outcome of the NYISO
7 The Sherman Act provides that Ielvery contract,
combination in the form of trust or otherwise, or
conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce among
the several States, or with foreign nations, is
declared to be illegal.’’ 15 U.S.C. § 1.
VerDate Mar<15>2010
19:41 Mar 13, 2012
Jkt 226001
auctions.8 Morgan Stanley’s net profit
from the derivatives was $21.6 million.9
The NYISO pays the market clearing
price to all sellers, including those who
offered capacity at a lower price. As a
result, the total economic damage to
electric customers exceeds the ill-gotten
gains of Morgan Stanley and the two
utilities. There is no quantification or
estimate of this damage to the public
and to customers in the Complaint or
other papers in the record. One major
capacity buyer, Consolidated Edison
Company of New York, Inc. (‘‘Con
Edison’’), estimated the inflated
capacity costs to be approximately $159
Million in 2006.10
Simultaneously with the filing of the
complaint, and without further
proceedings, DOJ and Morgan Stanley
filed a proposed Final Judgment, which
embodies their agreement to settle the
case. Key provisions of the Final
Judgment are:
• Morgan Stanley admits no
wrongdoing and the lawsuit is
terminated,
• Morgan Stanley agrees to disgorge
to the government only $4.8 million of
its $21.6 million profit from its
derivative contracts.
Standard of Review
The Tunney Act establishes the
procedure and standard of review
applicable to the proposed settlement of
an antitrust case brought by DOJ:
(1) Before entering any consent
judgment proposed by the United States
under this section, the court shall
determine that the entry of such
judgment is in the public interest. For
the purpose of such determination, the
court shall consider—
(A) the competitive impact of such
judgment, including termination of
8 There was little risk of low prices that would
require Keyspan to pay Morgan Stanley and Morgan
Stanley to pay Astoria under the derivatives.
Keyspan was able to set the clearing price because
at least some of its capacity would be needed, and
so it could confidently demand the ceiling price for
all or most of it, confident that when some of its
expensively priced capacity went unsold, it would
receive payments from Morgan Stanley in
accordance their derivative agreement. Keyspan
‘‘consistently bid its capacity at its cap even though
a significant portion of its capacity went unsold.’’
Complaint, p. 9, ¶ 32.
9 Complaint, p. 9, ¶ 35.
10 Of that amount, approximately $119 million
was paid by New York City area utilities, and $39
million was paid by utilities in the rest of the state.
See Motion to Continent of Consolidated Edison
Company of New York, Inc., etc., Re New York
Independent System Operator, FERC Docket No.
ER07–360 (Jan. 27, 2009), P. 2 and Affidavit of
Stuart Nachmias, ¶¶ 13–14, available at https://
elibrary.ferc.gov/idmws/common/opennatasp?
filelD=11236060. The amount of capacity
overcharges in 2007 and until NYISO capacity
market rules were changed in early 2008 were not
estimated.
PO 00000
Frm 00110
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
15131
alleged violations, provisions for
enforcement and modification, duration
of relief sought, anticipated effects of
alternative remedies actually
considered, whether its terms are
ambiguous, and any other competitive
considerations bearing upon the
adequacy of such judgment that the
court deems necessary to a
determination of whether the consent
judgment is in the public interest, and
(B) the impact of entry of such
judgment upon competition in the
relevant market or markets, upon the
public generally and individuals
alleging specific injury from the
violations set forth in the complaint
including consideration of the public
benefit, if any, to be derived from a
determination of the issues at trial.
15 U.S.C. § 16(e)(1). (Emphasis
added). The Tunney Act standard was
recently applied in the context of the
DOJ settlement with Keyspan, involving
the same derivative contract:
[T]he Tunney Act allows courts to
weigh, among other things, the
relationship between the allegations set
forth in the government’s complaint and
the remedy imposed by the proposed
final judgment, whether the proposed
final judgment is overly ambiguous,
whether the enforcement mechanisms it
employs are adequate, and whether the
proposed final judgment may
affirmatively prejudice third parties. See
United States v. Microsoft Corp., 56
F.3d 1448, 1461–62 (DCCir. 1995) (per
curiam). The court may not, however,
‘‘make a de novo determination of facts
and issues’’ in conducting its public
interest inquiry. United States v.
Western Elec. Co., 993 F.2d 1572, 1577
(DCCir.), cert. denied, 510 U.S. 984, 114
S.Ct. 487, 126 L.Ed.2d 438 (1993)
(internal quotation and citation
omitted). Rather, ‘‘jtjhe balancing of
competing social and political interests
affected by a proposed antitrust decree
must be left, in the first instance, to the
discretion of the Attorney General.’’ Id.
(internal quotation and citation
omitted). The court should therefore
reject the proposed final judgment only
if ‘‘it has exceptional confidence that
adverse antitrust consequences will
result—perhaps akin to the confidence
that would justify a court in overturning
the predictive judgments of an
administrative agency.’’ Microsoft, 56
F.3d at 1460 (internal quotations and
citation omitted).
In conducting its inquiry, the court is
not required to hold a hearing or
conduct a trial. See 119 Cong. Rec.
24,598 (1973); United States v. Airline
Tariff Pub. Co., 836 F.Supp. 9, 11 n. 2
(D.D.C. 1993). The Tunney Act
expressly allows the court to make its
E:\FR\FM\14MRN1.SGM
14MRN1
15132
Federal Register / Vol. 77, No. 50 / Wednesday, March 14, 2012 / Notices
Argument
1. The Proposed Settlement Is Not in
the Public Interest Because It Provides
No Benefit to Customers Harmed.
The Morgan Stanley/Keyspan/Astoria
derivatives supported gaming of the
NYISO market, causing very serious
financial harm to customers by
artificially inflating the NYISO market
prices for electric capacity. The DOJ
Complaint and Competitive Impact
Statement (‘‘CIS’’) very prominently
state that the ‘‘likely effect’’ of the
alleged antitrust violation ‘‘was to
increase capacity prices for the retail
electricity suppliers who must purchase
capacity, and, in turn, to increase the
prices consumers pay for electricity.’’
Complaint, pp. 1–2, CIS 1–2 (emphasis
added). The prayer for relief in the DOJ
Complaint includes a request for
equitable relief to ‘‘dissipate the
anticompetitive effects of the violation.’’
Complaint If 40. The only
‘‘anticompetitive effects’’ identified in
the record are the artificial increase in
NYISO prices and the higher prices paid
by consumers.
The record at this stage contains no
evidence of the magnitude of the injury
to consumers, including many AARP
members living in the New York City
area. As previously discussed, there are
indications outside the record that the
price of capacity was artificially raised
by approximately $157 million in 2006
by the gambit supported by the Morgan
Stanley derivatives, and the term of the
agreements went beyond 2006. The New
York State Public Service Commission
stated in its comments on the settlement
of the Keyspan case arising from the
same transactions that the harm to
consumers ‘‘could have totaled
hundreds of millions of
dollars.* * *’’ 12 The CIS does not
attempt to address the magnitude of this
harm to customers, which far exceeded
the total profits of the participants in the
scheme to raise NYISO prices.13 As a
consequence, the record is insufficiently
developed for a reviewing court to test
whether the remedy proposed is
appropriate.
Under the proposed settlement there
is not one penny for the injured
consumers. Instead, the entire $4.8
million of monetary relief is to be paid
to the United States Treasury. This does
nothing to address the injury to those
most directly harmed, the electric
customers whose bills were artificially
increased. There is no explanation in
the CIS of why this is so.
The Tunney Act requires DOJ, in its
CIS, to provide ‘‘a description and
evaluation of alternatives to such
proposal actually considered by the
United States.’’ 15 U.S.C. § 16(b)(6). The
CIS, however, contains no description
or evaluation of alternative relief that
would provide at least some benefit to
the injured customers. Any claim by
DOJ that equitable relief for the benefit
of injured consumers was never
‘‘actually considered’’ would not be
credible. In the Keyspan case, involving
the same derivative agreement, the
11 There must be ‘‘a factual foundation for the
government’s decision such that its conclusions
regarding the proposed settlement are reasonable.’’
United States v. Keyspan Corp., 763 F. Supp. 2d
633, 637–38 (S.D.N.Y. 2011) (quoting United States
v. Abitibi-Consolidated Inc., 584 F. Supp. 2d 162,
165 (D.D.C. 2008).
12 NYPSC Comments in United States v. Keyspan,
available at https://www.justice_gov/atr/cases/
f259700/259704-5.htm.
13 The total harm is greater than the profits
because under NYISO market rules, artificially high
prices achieved by participants in the scheme were
paid to all sellers.
srobinson on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
public interest determination on the
basis of the competitive impact
statement and response to comments
alone. A court may, in its discretion,
invoke additional procedures when it
determines such proceedings may assist
in the resolution of issues raised by the
comments. See H.R. Rep. No. 93–1463,
at 8–9 (1974), reprinted in U.S.S.C.A.N.
6535, 6539.
United States v. Keyspan, 763
F.Supp.2d 633, 637–638 (S.D.N.Y. 2011)
(‘‘Keyspan’’), quoting United States v.
Enova Corp., 107 F.Supp.2d 10, 17
(D.D.C. 2000) (emphasis added). It is not
necessary for the relief proposed in a
settlement to be a perfect remedy for the
alleged antitrust violation, but there
must be a factual basis to support any
DOJ conclusions that the remedies
proposed are reasonably adequate.11
The Keyspan decision, quoted above,
misapprehends the standard of review.
The Tunney Act not only ‘‘allows’’
courts to consider the listed factors in
its review. It requires such
consideration. The Tunney Act was
amended in the Antitrust Criminal
Penalty Enhancement and Reform Act of
2004 specifically to clarify that
reviewing courts ‘‘shall’’ (instead of
‘‘may’’) take each of the *enumerated
factors into account in their review of a
proposed antitrust case settlement. 15
U.S.C. §§ 16(e)(1)(A) and (B).
AARP demonstrates below that the
proposed settlement fails to pass muster
under the standards for approval of DOJ
antitrust settlements. DOJ should
withdraw its consent to the settlement,
and conduct further proceedings to
develop the record and proceed to trial,
if a renegotiated agreement which
addresses the concerns in these
comments cannot be made.
VerDate Mar<15>2010
19:41 Mar 13, 2012
Jkt 226001
PO 00000
Frm 00111
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
settlement also provided no relief to
consumers. The absence of any
equitable relief for consumers drew
vigorous protest in that case, in the
comments of the New York State Public
Service Commission, the New York
State Consumer Protection Board, the
City of New York, Con Edison, and
AARP. Surely DOJ would at least have
considered, however briefly, whether to
seek some measure of relief for electric
customers who suffered from the wrong.
AARP expects that DOJ, in its
response to these comments, will cite
the recent court approval of the Keyspan
settlement, which lacked any relief to
customers. That, however, does not bar
inclusion of such relief in the settlement
of this case.
In rejecting requests for equitable
relief to consumers the court in the
Keyspan case relied upon a perceived
‘‘filed rate’’ barrier and potential
‘‘transaction costs’’ of administering
monetary relief to customers, stating:
Finally, this Court rejects the notion
that the Consent Decree should only be
approved if the disgorged proceeds are
returned to New York City consumers.
While such relief might be optimal,
payment of the disgorged proceeds to
the Treasury is nevertheless ‘‘within the
reaches of the public interest.’’ Alex.
Brown, 963 F. Supp. at 238 (quotations
omitted). It can be effectuated without
incurring transaction costs and inures to
the public benefit. See Sec. & Exchange
Commin v. Bear, Steams & Co. Inc:, 626
F. Supp. 2d 402,419 (S.D.N.Y. 2009)
(answering ‘‘the question of how
[disgorged money] can be used to do
’the greatest good for the greatest
number of people’ by ordering its
transfer to the ‘‘Treasury to be used by
the Government for its operations’’).
Moreover, the Government raises
valid concerns regarding potential
violation of the filed-rate doctrine.
‘‘The filed rate doctrine bars suits
against regulated utilities grounded on
the allegation that the rates charged by
the utility are unreasonable. Simply
stated, the doctrine holds that any ‘filed
rate’—that is, one approved by the
governing regulatory agency is per se
reasonable and unassailable in judicial
proceedings brought by ratepayers.’’
Wegoland Ltd. v. NYNEX Corp., 27 F.3d
17, 18–19 (2d Cir. 1994); see also Keogh
v. Chi. & Northwestern Ry. Co., 260 U.S.
156, 163 (1922) (holding that the filed
rate doctrine bars recovery for antitrust
damages against carriers colluding to set
artificially high shipment rates). In view
of that prohibition, return of the
disgorged proceeds to New York City
electricity customers could circumvent
the filed-rate doctrine. A court must
extend ‘‘deference to the Government’s
E:\FR\FM\14MRN1.SGM
14MRN1
Federal Register / Vol. 77, No. 50 / Wednesday, March 14, 2012 / Notices
srobinson on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
evaluation of the case and the remedies
available to it.’’ Alex. Brown, 963 F.
Supp. at 239.
United States v. Keyspan Corp., 763 F.
Supp. 2d 633, 643 (S.D.N.Y. 2011)
(S.D.N.Y 2011) (emphasis added).
This case does not involve any utility
rate filed by Morgan Stanley. It involves
profits extracted from large numbers of
customers by sellers using Morgan
Stanley’s services and derivative
instruments as tools. Thus the ‘‘filed
rate’’ rationale for not providing any
relief to customers, perceived by the
court to be a barrier in Keyspan,14
clearly is not applicable here.
The transaction cost issue perceived
to be a barrier to customer relief in
Keyspan is also easily hurdled. Just as
utilities paid artificially inflated NYISO
charges for capacity and passed those
charges on to their customers, utilities
can pass on equitable monetary relief
intended for the benefit of their
customers in the normal course of
business without excessive transaction
costs. For example, Con Edison passes
on variations in capacity costs to its
customers every month, in monthly rate
adjustments, through its ‘‘Market
Adjustment Clause.’’ The Market
Adjustment Clause takes into account
36 variable factors every month,
including ‘‘(8) certain NYISO-related
charges and credits * * *.’’ 15 is
Equitable monetary relief from the
inflated NYISO charges could be
provided as a credit to customers in the
normal course of making rate
adjustments. Refunds to utility
customers relating to past overcharges
are also a well-established remedy.
Section 113 of the New York Public
Service Law provides:
2. Whenever any public utility
company or municipality, whose rates
are subject to the jurisdiction of the
commission, shall receive any refund of
amounts charged and collected from it
by any source, the commission shall
have power after a hearing, upon its
own motion, upon complaint or upon
the application of such public utility
company or municipality, to determine
whether or not such refund should be
passed on, in whole or in part, to the
consumers of such public utility
company or municipality and to order
such public utility company or
municipality to pass such refunds on to
14 At issue was Keyspan’s $48 million profit from
its derivative contract with Morgan Stanley. As the
contract was neither filed nor part of Keyspan’s
rates, which are set by the NYISO in its auctions,
applicability of the ‘‘filed rate’’ doctrine to customer
relief in that case is questionable.
15 Con Edison Electric Service Tariff, General
Information, Part VII, A(1)(a)(8), available at https://
www.coned.com/documents/elec/159-164a.pdf.
VerDate Mar<15>2010
19:41 Mar 13, 2012
Jkt 226001
its consumers, in the manner and to the
extent determined just and reasonable
by the commission.
The New York State Public Service
Commission supported the return of
overcharges as equitable relief to
customers in Keyspan. Surely the Public
Service Commission would cooperate, if
necessary in the oversight of monetary
relief intended for utility customers
when a provision for such relief is
contained in an antitrust case
settlement.
In sum, unlike Keyspan, there is no
‘‘filed rate’’ barrier in this case, and
AARP has demonstrated that consumer
benefits could be efficiently
administered without the speculative
transaction costs feared in Keyspan. The
proposed remedy allowing the
government to receive all the profits that
Morgan Stanley agrees to cede, without
consideration of the amount of harm
suffered by customers and without any
equitable relief to the customers, is not
equitable and is not in the public
interest.
2. The CIS Should Be Withdrawn or
Amended by DOJ To Support Its
Reasons for Termination of the Action
With No Finding of Wrongdoing by
Morgan Stanley.
As required by the Tunney Act, DOJ
filed a Competitive Impact Statement
(‘‘CIS’’) 16 in which it sets out the facts
of the case, its reasoning and its
conclusions in support of the
settlement. The DOJ Antitrust Division
Manual, 4th Ed., states that in a CIS,
‘‘[a]ll material provisions of the
proposed judgment should be
discussed.’’ Id., at IV–57. Notably
missing from the CIS in this case,
however, is any discussion by DOJ of
the critical provision which allows
termination of the case with no
admission of any wrongdoing by
Morgan Stanley. The proposed final
judgment states that Morgan Stanley:
consented to the entry of this Final
Judgment without trial or adjudication
of any issue of fact or law, for settlement
purposes only, and without this Final
Judgment constituting any evidence
against or an admission by Morgan for
any purpose with respect to any claim
or allegation contained in the Complaint
* * *.
Proposed Final Judgment, p. 1. The
importance of this provision letting
Morgan Stanley off the hook is
underscored by the Complaint, in which
DOJ demands ‘‘What the Court adjudge
and decree that the Morgan/Keyspan
Swap constitutes an illegal restraint in
the sale of installed capacity in the New
16 The CIS is available at https://www.justice.gov/
atr/cases/f275800/275857.pdf.
PO 00000
Frm 00112
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
15133
York City market in violation of Section
1 of the Sherman Act.’’ Complaint, ¶ 39.
Also, DOJ makes numerous references
in the CIS to Morgan Stanley’s conduct
as having constituted a violation of the
Sherman Act:
The United States brought this
lawsuit against Defendant Morgan
Stanley * * * to remedy a violation of
Section 1 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C.
§ 1. [CIS 1]
The proposed Final Judgment
remedies this violation * * * [CIS 2].
Disgorgement will deter Morgan and
others from future violations of the
antitrust laws. [CIS 2]
[D]isgorgement will effectively fulfill
the remedial goals of the Sherman Act
to ‘‘prevent and restrain’’ antitrust
violations as it will send a message of
deterrence to those in the financial
services community considering the use
of derivatives for anticompetitive ends.
[CIS 9]
Despite these assertions by DOJ in its
CIS that there were violations of the
law, it is the Final Judgment that counts
most. The Final Judgment affirmatively
disavows any finding or admission that
the law was violated by Morgan Stanley.
There is no explanation or factual basis
in the CIS to support DOJ’s
abandonment in the Final Judgment of
the primary object of the action. It is
incumbent upon DOJ to withdraw and
amend its CIS to include its rationale for
ending the case with no finding or
admission that Morgan Stanley violated
the antitrust laws, and with no
commitment by Morgan Stanley that it
will not engage in similar conduct in the
future. The public should then be
allowed an additional opportunity to
respond to any amended or new CIS.
With no finding that Section 1 of the
Sherman Act is violated by the use of
financial derivatives to backstop risks
when sellers game electricity markets,
no one, including Morgan Stanley,
really knows whether this gambit is
actually illegal. As a result, Morgan
Stanley and any other future
wrongdoers will still lack scienter, an
essential element for criminal sanctions
under Section 2 of the Sherman Act.
Thus, future wrongdoers can try the
gambit again and need be concerned
only about trivial civil sanctions.
3. DOJ Should Withdraw its Consent
to the Settlement or Amend its CIS to
Provide Support for its Conclusion that
the Disgorgement Proposed in this Case
will be a Deterrent.
Disgorgement of profits is one of the
equitable remedies available to address
violations of the Sherman Act. United
States v. Keyspan Corp., 763 F. Supp. 2d
633, 638–641 (SDNY 2011). DOJ
repeatedly emphasizes the settlement’s
E:\FR\FM\14MRN1.SGM
14MRN1
srobinson on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
15134
Federal Register / Vol. 77, No. 50 / Wednesday, March 14, 2012 / Notices
requirement that Morgan Stanley
disgorge $4.8 million of its profits from
the derivatives, claiming this payment
to the government would serve as a
deterrent:
Disgorgement will deter Morgan and
others from future violations of the
antitrust laws. [CIS 2]
The proposed Final Judgment requires
Morgan to disgorge profits gained as a
result of its unlawful agreement
restraining trade. Morgan is to surrender
$4.8 million to the Treasury of the
United States. [CIS 8]
*
*
*
*
*
Requiring disgorgement in these
circumstances will thus protect the
public interest by deterring Morgan and
other parties from entering into similar
financial agreements that result in
anticompetitive effects in the
underlying markets, or from otherwise
engaging in similar anticompetitive
conduct in the future. [CIS 8]
A disgorgement remedy should deter
Morgan and others from engaging in
similar conduct and thus achieves a
significant portion of the relief the
United States would have obtained
through litigation * * * [CIS 11]
There is no evidence in the record,
however, to support these broad claims
that the settlement crafted by Morgan
Stanley and DOJ would have any
deterrent effect on anyone.
According to the CIS, ‘‘Morgan earned
approximately $21.6 million in net
revenues from the Morgan/Keyspan
Swap and the Morgan/Astoria Hedge.’’
CIS 6 DOJ acknowledges that only a
portion of Morgan Stanley’s profits
would be disgorged if the proposed
settlement is approved, attempting to
put the best light on a small recovery:
While the disgorged sum represents
less than all of Morgan’s net transaction
revenues under the two agreements, [fn.
omitted] disgorgement will effectively
fulfill the remedial goals of the Sherman
Act to ‘‘prevent and restrain’’ antitrust
violations as it will send a message of
deterrence to those in the financial
services community considering the use
of derivatives for anticompetitive ends.
[CIS 9] (emphasis added).
If the 21% to be disgorged under the
proposed settlement is ‘‘less than all’’ of
the $21.6 million profit, as DOJ puts it,
perhaps the amount of ill-gotten gains
retained by Morgan Stanley—$16.8
million, or 79%—might be said to be
‘‘nearly all’’ of the net profit.
The CIS fails to explain how
disgorgement of only $4.8 million, and
allowing Morgan Stanley to keep $16.8
million of its profits from the scheme
would deter similar future conduct by
Morgan Stanley or anyone. There is
VerDate Mar<15>2010
19:41 Mar 13, 2012
Jkt 226001
simply no evidence in the record to
support DOJ’s conclusion that the
proposed settlement ‘‘will send a
message of deterrence to those in the
financial services community
considering the use of derivatives for
anticompetitive ends.’’ Id. Given the
minimal development of the record, no
one can see the derivative instruments
used by Morgan Stanley. If the offending
derivative agreements are not disclosed,
there is even less likelihood of deterring
similar transactions by others. These
should have been provided by DOJ with
the CIS as ‘‘determinative documents.17
DOJ is ordinarily entitled to deference
in assessing the effectiveness of a
remedy it agrees to, but here its
conclusion that disgorgement of only
$4.8 million is sufficient is refuted by
every day common sense and
arithmetic. The CIS does not explain in
plain language how allowing a
wrongdoer to keep 79% of its ill-gotten
gains can be seen as any kind of
‘‘message of deterrent.’’ Rather, the
‘‘message’’ to some may really be that
large profits can still be made from
gaming electricity markets using
financial derivative agreements to
support bidding strategies. If found out,
there will probably be no criminal
antitrust sanction, and at worst one may
keep the majority of the profit in a
settlement with DOJ. The real lesson
taught by the proposed settlement to
potential manipulators could actually
encourage similar conduct and further
harm competition. This is not a remote
or speculative concern. ‘‘Manipulation
is a potentially serious problem in all
derivatives markets, energy
included.’’ 18 The CIS does not consider
this possibility and therefore does not
sufficiently address the impact on
competition as required by the Tunney
Act. 15 U.S.C. § 16(e)(1)(A).
The $4.8 million disgorgement is
probably well within the range of what
Morgan Stanley’s litigation expenses
might be if the case is litigated. The real
lesson of the disclaimer and the small
disgorgement is that this is merely a
nuisance settlement. As recently stated
by Judge Rakoff in the course of
rejecting a settlement proposed of the
SEC:
[A] consent judgment that does not
involve any admissions and that results
in only very modest penalties is just as
frequently viewed, particularly in the
17 The DOJ Competitive Impact Statement asserts
there are no ‘‘determinative’’ documents required to
be submitted under the Tunney Act. See United
States v. Central Contracting Co., Inc., 537 F. Supp.
571 (E.D. Va. 1982).
18 Craig Pirrong, Energy Market Manipulation:
Definition, Diagnosis, and Deterrence, 31 Energy
Law Journal 1–2 (2010) (emphasis added).
PO 00000
Frm 00113
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
business community, as a cost of doing
business imposed by having to maintain
a working relationship with a regulatory
agency, rather than as any indication of
where the real truth lies.
SEC v Citigroup Global Markets, Inc.,
11 Civ. 7387 (Nov. 28, 2011).
4. The CIS Fails to Support the Claim
that the Settlement is Reasonable
Because it Avoids Litigation Risk.
DOJ attempts to justify the proposed
settlement by invoking its risk of
litigation, i.e., that it might lose the case
if it goes to trial:
The $4.8 million disgorgement
amount is the product of settlement and
accounts for litigation risks and costs.
[CIS 9]
Had the case against Morgan
proceeded to trial, the United States
would have sought disgorgement of the
$21.6 million in net transaction
revenues Morgan earned under both the
Morgan/Keyspan Swap and the Morgan/
Astoria Hedge. At trial, Morgan—in
addition to raising arguments as to its
lack of liability in general—would have
disputed that the entire $21.6 million
earned under both agreements would be
cognizable as ill-gotten gains. [CIS 9, fn
4].
While DOJ is ordinarily given
considerable deference to its assessment
of the merits of its case, it does not cite
any authority or facts to show that this
case is difficult. Based on the CIS and
the record, there are written derivative
contracts evidencing the profit-sharing
arrangement of the utility
counterparties, facilitated by Morgan
Stanley as middleman. The utilities’
bidding records should be readily
available from the NYISO. What is the
problem with the case? DOJ gives no
hint that its case is in any way doubtful.
This case is only a variation on classic
bid-rigging and price fixing. Here,
Keyspan bid high, in order to elevate the
auction price paid to all sellers, Astoria
paid Morgan Stanley some of the extra
profits it made due to the elevated price,
and Morgan Stanley paid Keyspan,
keeping a net $21.6 million profit for its
services in facilitating the price raising
game. Had the utility sellers made an
agreement bilaterally with the same
results, it would be seen as a crystal
clear antitrust violation. See Addyston
Pipe & Steel Co. v. United States, 175
US 211, 243 (1899) (‘‘the defendants
enter, not in truth as competitors, but
under an agreement or combination
among themselves which eliminates all
competition between them for the
contract, and permits one of their
number to make his own bid and
requires the others to bid over him’’). It
should be equally clear that a
middleman like Morgan Stanley, who
E:\FR\FM\14MRN1.SGM
14MRN1
srobinson on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
Federal Register / Vol. 77, No. 50 / Wednesday, March 14, 2012 / Notices
effectuates the economic alignment of
the sellers with its derivative
agreements, is part of the ‘‘combination’’
and is also a Sherman Act violator.
The CIS makes an exaggerated claim
that DOJ has won victory in the
proposed settlement, stating:
A disgorgement remedy should deter
Morgan and others from engaging in
similar conduct and thus achieves a
significant portion of the relief the
United States would have obtained
through litigation. * * * [CIS 11]
(emphasis added).
If the $4.8 million to be disgorged is
‘‘a significant portion’’ of the relief
sought in the complaint, then the $16.8
million retained by Morgan Stanley
could be said to be three times as
‘‘significant’’ because Morgan Stanley
keeps the bulk of its profit from
facilitating the scheme.
5. The Keyspan Case Is Not A Barrier
to a Consumer Remedy in This Case.
DOJ relies heavily on the prior
decision approving the settlement of its
antitrust case against Keyspan,
involving the same derivative contract,
where $12 million of Keyspan’s $48
million profit was disgorged, with no
equitable relief for consumers:
Keyspan, pursuant to a Final
Judgment sought by the United States,
has surrendered $12 million as a result
of its role in the Morgan/Keyspan
Swap.3 See United States v. Keyspan
Corp., 763 T. Supp. 2d 633,637–38
(S.D.N.Y. 2011). Securing similar
disgorgement from the other responsible
party to the anticompetitive agreement
will protect the public interest by
depriving Morgan of a substantial
portion of the fruits of the agreement.
The effect of the swap agreement was to
effectively combine the economic
interests of Keyspan and Astoria,
thereby permitting Keyspan to increase
prices above competitive rates, and this
result could not have been achieved
without Morgan’s participation in the
swap agreement. Requiring
disgorgement in these circumstances
will thus protect the public interest by
deterring Morgan and other parties from
entering into similar financial
agreements that result in
anticompetitive effects in the
underlying markets, or from otherwise
engaging in similar anticompetitive
conduct in the future.
CIS 8, (emphasis added). If
disgorgement of $4.8 million constitutes
a ‘‘substantial portion of the fruits of the
agreement,’’ then the amount of illgotten profits retained by Morgan
Stanley is three times as ‘‘substantial.’’
As the emphasized language in the
quotation above shows, the successful
gaming of the NYISO market could not
VerDate Mar<15>2010
19:41 Mar 13, 2012
Jkt 226001
have been achieved by the utilities
without Morgan Stanley acting as
middleman. It was not something
Keyspan and Astoria could have
accomplished themselves in a bilateral
agreement without flagrant and knowing
violation of antitrust law, which might
expose them to possible criminal
charges and large fines under Section 2
of the Sherman Act. Because its role as
middleman was crucial to the scheme,
it is appropriate to require Morgan
Stanley to disgorge proportionately
more than Keyspan, not less.
The proposed settlement not only
fails to ‘‘deprive the antitrust defendants
of the benefits of their conspiracy.’’ Intl
Boxing Club v. United States, 358 U.S.
242 at 253 (1959). (quotation omitted),
it does not even come close to that goal.
Instead, it allows Morgan Stanley to
retain the lion’s share, 79%, of the
benefits. ‘‘[A]dequate relief in a
monopolization case should * * *
deprive the defendants of any of the
benefits of the illegal conduct * * *’’
United States v. Grinnell Corp., 384 U.S.
563, 577 (1966). Accord, United States
v. E.I. du Pont de Nemours & Co., 366
U.S. 316, 368 (1961) (‘‘Those who
violate the Act may not reap the benefits
of their violations * * *’’ (quotations
omitted)). In any settlement parties may
obtain something less in the
compromise than they initially sought
when commencing the litigation, but the
woefully trivial disgorgement by
Morgan Stanley of only $4.8 million of
its profits cannot possibly be an
adequate equitable remedy or in the
public interest.
AARP Recommendations
AARP recommends that DOJ
withdraw from the proposed settlement
and proceed in the litigation, or
renegotiate with Morgan Stanley to
include the following in any new or
revised settlement agreement:
A. Allocation of profits made by
Morgan Stanley to provide equitable
relief to electric utility consumers
harmed by the violation,
B. Admission by Morgan Stanley of its
violation of the Sherman Act as
described in the Complaint,
C. Quantification of the total harm to
consumers and markets, and
D. Disgorgement by Morgan Stanley of
all profits it realized from the
derivatives used to implement the price
raising scheme.
PO 00000
15135
STATE OF NEW YORK DEPARTMENT
OF PUBLIC SERVICE
THREE EMPIRE STATE PLAZA,
ALBANY, NY 12223–1350
www.dps.state.ny.us
PUBLIC SERVICE COMMISSION
GARRY A. BROWN
Chairman
PATRICIA L ACAMPORA
MAUREEN F. HARRIS
ROBERT E. CURRY JR.
JAMES L LAROCCA
Commissioners
PETER McGOWAN
General Counsel
JACLYN A. BRILLING
Secretary
December 30, 2011
VIA E-MAIL
William H. Stallings, Chief,
Transportation Energy & Agriculture
Section, Antitrust Division, United
States Department of Justice,
Washington, DC 20530, E-Mail:
william.stallings@usdoj.gov.
Re: United States of America v. Morgan
Stanley, Civil Case No. 11–civ–6875
Comments of the Public Service
Commission of the State of New York
Dear Chief Stallings:
Pursuant to the Tunney Act, 15 U.S.C.
§ 16(e)(1), enclosed please find
comments of the Public Service
Commission of the State of New York in
response to the notice published in the
Federal Register on October 11, 2011.
See U.S. Dep’t of Justice, Antitrust Div.,
United States v. Morgan Stanley,
Proposed Final Judgment and
Competitive Impact Statement, 76
Federal Register 62843 (October 11,
2011).
Please contact me at (518) 474–7663,
if you have any questions. Thank you.
Very truly yours,
Sean Mullany
Assistant Counsel
Enclosure
IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT
COURT FOR THE SOUTHERN
DISTRICT OF NEW YORK
Civil Case No. 11–civ–6875, United
States of America, Plaintiff v. Morgan
Stanley, Defendant.
COMMENTS OF THE PUBLIC SERVICE
COMMISSION OF THE STATE OF
NEW YORK, PURSUANT TO THE
ANTITRUST PROCEDURES AND
PENALTIES ACT, ON THE PROPOSED
FINAL JUDGMENT
SUMMARY
The Public Service Commission of the
State of New York (‘‘PSC’’) submits
Frm 00114
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
E:\FR\FM\14MRN1.SGM
14MRN1
srobinson on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
15136
Federal Register / Vol. 77, No. 50 / Wednesday, March 14, 2012 / Notices
these comments pursuant to the
Antitrust Procedures and Penalties Act,
15 U.S.C. §§ 16(b)–(h), in response to
the notice published in the Federal
Register on October 11, 2011, in this
matter. U.S. Dep’t of Justice, Antitrust
Div., United States v. Morgan Stanley,
Proposed Final Judgment and
Competitive Impact Statement, 76
Federal Register 62843 (October 11,
2011).
The Department of Justice (‘‘DOJ’’) is
to be commended for its faithful
enforcement of the antitrust law to
protect the integrity of electricity
markets in New York City. The electric
capacity market for New York City is
highly concentrated. The antitrust law is
properly applied in this case to address
wrongful anti-competitive practices of
Morgan Stanley. DOJ’s enforcement of
the antitrust law is critical to protect
consumers against the harmful effects of
Morgan Stanley’s anti-competitive
conduct in this case and, more
generally, to protect the public interest
in the integrity of the newly-created
competitive electricity markets.
DOJ proposes to settle this litigation
by having Morgan Stanley pay the
United States government $4.8 million.
DOJ asserts such a settlement will be in
the public interest because Morgan
Stanley’s payment of this amount into
the U.S. Treasury will deprive Morgan
Stanley of ‘‘a substantial portion’’ of its
unjust enrichment. Competitive Impact
Statement, at 8. DOJ admits it seeks only
partial disgorgement of Morgan
Stanley’s ill-gotten gains, saying that, if
it proceeded to trial, it would have
sought disgorgement of all of Morgan
Stanley’s net transaction revenues,
which DOJ asserts were $21.6 million.
Competitive Impact Statement, at 9 & n.
4. DOJ nonetheless claims the lesser
amount of $4.8 million ‘‘will effectively
fulfill the remedial goals of the Sherman
Act’’ to ‘‘prevent and restrain’’ antitrust
violations because the settlement will
‘‘send a message of deterrence’’ to the
financial services community.
Competitive Impact Statement, at 9.
According to DOJ, the lesser amount of
$4.8 million will still prevent market
participants from using such financial
agreements to manipulate the capacity
markets in the future. Competitive
Impact Statement, at 8–9.
These claims are central to DOJ’s
assertion that the settlement is in the
public interest, a finding that the Court
must make in order to approve DOJ’s
proposal. DOJ, however, has offered
nothing to support its claims that this
settlement, which would allow Morgan
Stanley to retain almost 80 percent of its
ill-gotten gains, will deter such
anticompetitive conduct. Because of
VerDate Mar<15>2010
19:41 Mar 13, 2012
Jkt 226001
this, DOJ has not demonstrated that this
settlement will achieve a central
purpose of the Sherman Antitrust Act,
namely preventing anticompetitive
arrangements such as those facilitated
by Morgan Stanley in this case. POINT
I, below.
To remedy this, the Court should,
under the authority of the Tunney Act,
direct DOJ to supplement the record to
show how and why the settlement will
prevent such violations from recurring.
POINT II, below.
DOJ has not shown that a settlement
for $4.8 million would be reasonable.
DOT alleges Morgan Stanley’s net
revenues were $21.6 million. It asserts
that $4.8 million is reasonable given the
risks and costs of fully litigating the
case. However, DOJ has offered only a
summary statement of Morgan Stanley’s
anticipated position at trial. Competitive
Impact Statement, at 9 & n. 4. This
statement does not shed light on the
actual risks and costs of litigation.
Moreover, in considering whether a $4.8
million settlement would be reasonable,
the Court should weigh the nature of
Morgan Stanley’s wrongdoing, the
impact of such a settlement on DOJ’s
enforcement role, and the overall
efficacy of antitrust law as a mechanism
for preventing such harmful market
manipulation.
DOJ has already settled with KeySpan
for $12 million, an amount equal to 24.5
percent of KeySpan’s alleged wrongful
gain. That settlement was approved by
the court on February 2, 2011. United
States v. KeySpan Corporation, 10 Civ.
1415 (WHP) Memorandum and Order,
(S.D.N.Y. Feb. 2, 2011). Now DOJ
proposes to settle with Morgan Stanley,
the financial institution that allegedly
actively facilitated KeySpan’s wrongful
manipulation of the capacity market.
DOJ alleges that KeySpan, knowing it
could not directly buy an interest in
Astoria (its largest competitor), enlisted
Morgan Stanley to act as an
intermediary. Thus, Morgan Stanley’s
involvement was designed to allow
KeySpan to do indirectly what it could
not do directly. In effect, DOJ alleges
that Morgan Stanley actively facilitated
KeySpan’s attempt to evade the law.
Despite allegations of such egregious
conduct, DOJ proposes to settle with
Morgan Stanley for only 22.2 percent of
Morgan Stanley’s wrongful gain. Such
an arrangement, however, is more akin
to a tax than a penalty.
The settlement amount is particularly
unreasonable given the fact that Morgan
Stanley’s illegal conduct had a much
larger harmful impact. As the PSC noted
in its comments on DOJ’s earlier
settlement with KeySpan, the illegal
market manipulation that KeySpan and
PO 00000
Frm 00115
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
Morgan Stanley orchestrated imposed
unnecessary costs on consumers which
may have totaled tens of millions of
dollars. Even if DOJ could not recover
all those damages under the Sherman
Antitrust Act, the reasonableness of
seeking only 22.2 percent of what DOJ
can recover should be measured, in part
at least, by the larger consumer harm
KeySpan and Morgan Stanley caused.
United States v. KeySpan Corporation,
10 Civ. 1415 (S.D.N.Y.) (WHP),
Comments of the Public Service
Commission of the State of New York,
Pursuant To the Antitrust Procedures
and Penalties Act, On the Proposed
Finaljudgment, (Apr. 30, 2010). POINT
III, below.
BACKGROUND
In this civil antitrust action, brought
DOJ under Section 1 of the Sherman
Act, 15 U.S.C. § 1, the government seeks
equitable and other relief against
Morgan Stanley for violating the
antitrust law. According to DOJ, in late
2005 and early 2006, Morgan Stanley
entered into a ‘‘swap’’ agreement with
KeySpan Corporation (‘‘KeySpan’’), then
the largest electricity producer in the
New York City metropolitan area. DOJ
asserts this agreement (the ‘‘Morgan/
KeySpan Swap’’) ensured that KeySpan
would withhold substantial output from
the New York City electric generating
capacity market, thereby discouraging
competitive bidding and increasing
capacity prices. On or about the same
time, Morgan Stanley entered into an
offsetting ‘‘swap’’ agreement with
Astoria—KeySpan’s largest competitor
(the ‘‘Morgan/Astoria Swap’’). Morgan
Stanley, acting as the intermediary
between KeySpan and Astoria, extracted
revenues for its role. Thus, Morgan
Stanley facilitated an arrangement ‘‘[t]he
likely effect * * * was to increase
capacity prices for the retail electricity
suppliers who must purchase capacity,
and, in turn, to increase the prices
consumers pay for electricity.’’ 76
Federal Register, at 62844.
According to DOJ, the Morgan/
KeySpan Swap unlawfully restrained
competition in New York City’s electric
capacity market. KeySpan entered into
that agreement to protect itself against
increased losses from its preferred
bidding strategy, due to the entry of new
competitors into the capacity market. 76
Federal Register, at 62844. Under the
Morgan/KeySpan Swap, KeySpan,
which already possessed substantial
market power in the highly
concentrated and constrained New York
City capacity market, ‘‘enter[ed] into an
agreement that gave it a financial
interest in the capacity of Astoria—
KeySpan’s largest competitor.’’ 76
E:\FR\FM\14MRN1.SGM
14MRN1
Federal Register / Vol. 77, No. 50 / Wednesday, March 14, 2012 / Notices
Federal Register, at 62844. By giving
KeySpan revenues not only from its
own sales, but also from the capacity
sales of its largest competitor, the
Morgan/KeySpan Swap ‘‘effectively
eliminated KeySpan’s incentive to
compete for sales’’ of capacity. 76
Federal Register, at 62846. Thus, ‘‘[t]he
clear tendency of the Morgan/KeySpan
Swap was to alter KeySpan’s bidding in
the NYC Capacity Market auctions.’’ 76
Federal Register, at 62846.
As a result, electric capacity prices
remained unlawfully inflated, and
Morgan Stanley earned approximately
$21.6 million in net revenues from the
Morgan/KeySpan Swap and the
Morgan/Astoria Swap. 76 Federal
Register, at 62846. In addition, the
elimination of competitive pressures,
due to the anti-competitive Morgan/
KeySpan Swap imposed unnecessary
costs on consumers which may have
totaled tens of millions of dollars.
POINT I
srobinson on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
DOJ HAS NOT PROVIDED ENOUGH
INFORMATION TO DETERMINE
WHETHER THE PROPOSED
SETTLEMENT IS IN THE PUBLIC
INTEREST
Before entering any consent judgment
proposed by the United States, the court
must first determine that entry of such
a judgment ‘‘is in the public interest.’’
15 U.S.C. § 16(e)(1). In doing so, ‘‘the
court shall consider—
(A) the competitive impact of such
judgment, including termination of
alleged violations, provisions for
enforcement and modification, duration
of relief sought, anticipated effects of
alternative remedies actually
considered, whether its terms are
ambiguous, and any other competitive
considerations bearing upon the
adequacy of such judgment that the
court deems necessary to a
determination of whether the consent
judgment is in the public interest; and
(B) the impact of entry of such
judgment upon competition in the
relevant market or markets, upon the
public generally and individuals
alleging specific injury from the
violations set forth in the complaint
including consideration of the public
benefit, if any, to be derived from a
determination of the issues at trial.
15 U.S.C. § 16(e)(1)(A) &(B).
In seeking this Court’s approval, DOJ
has the burden to ‘‘provide a factual
basis for concluding that the settlements
are reasonably adequate remedies for
the alleged harms.’’ United States v.
SBC Communs., Inc., 489 F. Supp. 2d 1,
17 (D.D.C. 2007). In this case, DOJ has
not met this burden. Neither the
VerDate Mar<15>2010
19:41 Mar 13, 2012
Jkt 226001
competitive impact statement, nor the
proposed consent decree provides the
information needed to evaluate whether
this settlement would be a reasonably
adequate remedy for the harm caused by
KeySpan.
Under the proposed settlement,
Morgan Stanley would be required to
pay the United States government a total
of $4.8 million dollars. United States v.
Morgan Stanley, Proposed Final
Judgment and Competitive Impact
Statement, 76 Federal Register 62843,
9949 (October 11, 2011). According to
DOJ, this amount ‘‘remedies [Morgan
Stanley’s] violation by requiring Morgan
to disgorge profits obtained through the
anticompetitive agreement.’’ 76 Federal
Register, at 62846. According to DOJ,
‘‘[d]isgorgement will deter Morgan and
others from future violations of the
antitrust laws.’’ 76 Federal Register, at
62846. Thus, according to DOJ, the
public interest is served because the
proposed settlement will both prevent
Morgan Stanley’s unjust enrichment,
and will deter such wrongful conduct in
the future.
Preventing Morgan Stanley’s unjust
enrichment is a legitimate purpose of
any proposed settlement. In fashioning
relief in response to a violation of the
antitrust law, ‘‘[o]ne of [the] objectives
* * * is to ’deny to the defendant the
fruits of its statutory violation.’’
Massachusetts v. Microsoft Corp., 373
F.3d 1199, 1232 (DC Cir. 2004) (quoting
United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253
F.3d 34, 103 (DC Cir. 2001)). However,
the unstated premise underlying DOJ’s
claims (that disgorgement is necessary
to prevent unjust enrichment, and a $4.8
million penalty is adequate) is that
Morgan Stanley’s unjust enrichment
totaled only $4.8 million. Yet DOJ itself
asserts that Morgan Stanley’s net
revenues totaled $21.6 million. 76
Federal Register, at 62847. Thus, DOJ
itself acknowledges it is seeking only
partial disgorgement.
DOJ nonetheless claims such partial
disgorgement will ‘‘send a message of
deterrence[,]’’ thereby ‘‘deterring
Morgan and other parties from entering
into similar financial agreements ... or
from otherwise engaging in similar
anticompetitive conduct in the future.’’
76 Federal Register, at 62848. While
these claims are central to DOJ’s
contention that the settlement would be
in the public interest, DOJ has not
offered any evidence to support the
proposition that this settlement will act
as a deterrent. This lack of evidence
showing the settlement would prevent
and deter such conduct is a critical
omission. As DOJ acknowledges,
preventing and restraining antitrust
violations are ‘‘the remedial goals’’ of
PO 00000
Frm 00116
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
15137
the Sherman Antitrust Act. 76 Federal
Register; at 62848. Yet the absence of
any evidence supporting these claims
makes it virtually impossible for the
Court to meaningfully evaluate whether
a $4.8 million settlement ‘‘represents a
reasonable method of eliminating the
consequences of the illegal conduct.’’
National Soc. of Professional Engineers
v. United States, 435 U.S. 679, 698
(1978). This holds true both with
respect to depriving Morgan Stanley of
its unjust enrichment, and with respect
to evaluating whether the settlement
will deter such wrongful conduct in the
future. Thus, on the current record, the
Court has no basis for finding the
proposed settlement would be ‘‘in the
public interest.’’
Given what DOJ has presented, the
settlement would not be in the public
interest. DOJ seeks only partial
disgorgement, so the settlement would
not prevent Morgan Stanley’s unjust
enrichment, since anything less than
full disgorgement would not fully strip
Morgan Stanley of its wrongful gains.
The proposed settlement amount,
however, is only a minor fraction
(22.2%) of Morgan Stanley’s unjust
enrichment.1 Why would such a penalty
deter similar violations of the antitrust
law in the future? Common sense
suggests that such an amount will
instead be viewed as merely a cost of
doing business. S.E.C. v. Citigroup
Global Markets, Inc., Slip Op. at 10
(S.D.N.Y. Nov. 28, 2011) (‘‘[A] consent
judgment that does not involve any
admissions and that results in only very
modest penalties is just as frequently
viewed, particularly in the business
community, as a cost of doing business
imposed by having to maintain a
working relationship with a regulatory
agency * * *’’). Allowing Morgan
Stanley to retain almost 80 percent of its
ill-gotten gains can hardly be
characterized as an effective deterrent
without something more to support
1 In approving DOJ’s earlier $12 million
settlement with KeySpan, the court noted that,
according to DOJ, KeySpan ‘‘did not necessarily
earn additional revenues’’ by not competing.
Instead, the swap offered greater revenue certainty
even though ‘‘competing could have earned the
company greater revenues * * *’’ United States v.
KeySpan Corporation, 10 Civ. 1415 (WHP)
Memorandum and Order, at 14–15 (S.D.N.Y. Feb. 2,
2011). Because of this, in part, the Court found the
$12 million settlement with KeySpan to be
reasonable. Here, Morgan Stanley’s swap revenues
(aside from transactional costs) were profits since
it would have had no revenues if KeySpan
competed instead of entering into the swap.
Accordingly, the court’s rationale for finding the
KeySpan settlement amount reasonable does not
support this proposed settlement with Morgan
Stanley.
E:\FR\FM\14MRN1.SGM
14MRN1
15138
Federal Register / Vol. 77, No. 50 / Wednesday, March 14, 2012 / Notices
such a claim.2 Thus, the proposed $4.8
million settlement would not satisfy
either of DOJ’s rationales (i.e.,
preventing Morgan Stanley’s unjust
enrichment, and deterring such
wrongful conduct in the future) for a
judicial finding that the settlement is in
the public interest.
POINT II
srobinson on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
THE COURT SHOULD DIRECT DOJ TO
SUPPLEMENT THE RECORD ON THE
DETERRENT EFFECT(S) OF THE
PROPOSED SETTLEMENT
The Morgan/KeySpan Swap, in both
purpose and effect, violated the antitrust
law. Its purpose was to ‘‘effectively
eliminate[] KeySpan’s incentive to
compete for sales in the same way a
purchase of Astoria or a direct
agreement between KeySpan and
Astoria would have done.’’ 76 Federal
Register, at 62848. Thus, regardless of
its effect on the market, the Morgan/
KeySpan Swap violated the Sherman
Act. Cf. Summit Health v. Pinhas, 500
U.S. 322, 330 (1991) (1131ecause the
essence of any violation of § 1 [of the
Sherman Act] is the illegal agreement
itself[,] rather than the overt acts
performed in furtherance of it, * * *
proper analysis focuses, not upon actual
consequences, but rather upon the
potential harm that would ensue if the
conspiracy were successful’’).
The Morgan/KeySpan Swap also
violated the Sherman Act because of its
effect on the market. Its ‘‘clear
tendency’’ was to alter KeySpan’s
bidding, in order to prevent competition
and keep prices high. 76 Federal
Register, at 62848. CI United States v.
Stasztcuk, 517 F.2d 53, 60 & n.17 (7th
Cir. Ill. 1975) (‘‘The federal power to
protect the free market may be exercised
to punish conduct which threatens to
impair competition even when no actual
harm results’’).
However, because, as discussed in
POINT I, DOJ has not proffered evidence
sufficient to enable the Court to evaluate
whether the proposed settlement is in
the public interest, DOJ should be
directed to do so. Under-the Tunney
Act, ‘‘[t]he court may ‘take testimony of
Government officials or experts’ as it
deems appropriate, 15 U.S.C. 16(f)(1);
authorize participation by interested
2 Arguably, even total disgorgement would have
only a limited deterrent effect. ‘‘[T]o ’limit the
penalty * * * to disgorgement is to tell a violator
that he may [break the law] with virtual impunity;
if he gets away undetected, he can keep the
proceeds, but if caught, he simply has to be give
back the profits of his wrong.’’ SEC v. Bear, Stearns
& Co., 626 F. Supp. 2d 402,406 (S.D.N.Y. 2009)
(quoting SE.C. v. Rabinovich & Assoc., 2008 U.S.
Dist. LEXIS 93595, 2008 WL 4937360, at *6
(S.D.N.Y. Nov. 18, 2008)).
VerDate Mar<15>2010
19:41 Mar 13, 2012
Jkt 226001
persons, including appearances by
amici curiae, id. § 16(f)(3); review
comments and objections filed with the
Government concerning the proposed
judgment, as well as the Government’s
response thereto, id. § 16(f)(4); and ‘take
such other action in the public interest
as the court may deem appropriate,’ id.
§ 16(f)(5).’’ Massachusetts v. Microsoft
Corp., 373 F.3d 1199, 1206 (DC Cir.
2004).
Requiring DOJ to adduce facts relating
to whether such a minimal penalty will
prevent and deter such anti-competitive
conduct will provide a record basis for
any public interest determination made
by the Court. Cf. SE.0 v. Bank Of
America Corp., llll F.
Supp.2dllll, 2010 U.S. Dist. LEXIS
15460 (S.D.N.Y. Feb. 22, 2010)
(approving a proposed consent
judgment because, inter alia, after the
court rejected an earlier proposed
settlement, the parties conducted
extensive discovery which established
facts supporting the new proposal).
POINT III
THE REASONABLENESS OF THE
PROPOSED SETTLEMENT SHOULD BE
EVALUATED IN LIGHT OF THE
RATEPAYER HARM CAUSED BY
MORGAN STANLEY
In determining whether the settlement
is in ‘‘the public interest,’’ the Court
should consider the impact of the
proposed settlement on the ratepayers
that were harmed by Morgan Stanley’s
anti-competitive conduct. See 15 U.S.C.
§ 16(e)(1)(B) (‘‘the court shall consider
the impact of entry of such judgment
upon * * * the public generally
* * *’’).3 DOJ acknowledges ratepayers
were harmed, in the form of inflated
capacity prices, because of Morgan
Stanley’s conduct. According to DOJ,
‘‘[w]ithout the Morgan/KeySpan Swap,
KeySpan likely would have chosen from
a range of potentially profitable
competitive strategies in response to the
entry of new capacity. Had it done so,
the price of capacity would have
declined.’’ 76 Federal Register; at
62846. Because KeySpan decided to
withhold capacity rather than compete,
ratepayers were harmed in amounts far
exceeding Morgan Stanley’s $21.6
million in wrongful profit.
Yet, in its earlier settlement with
KeySpan, DOJ indicated ratepayers may
have no recourse under the antitrust law
because of the ‘‘filed rate’’ doctrine. See
75 Federal Register, at 9951. Moreover,
ratepayers may not be able to obtain any
3 Cf. United States v. SBC Communs., Inc., 489 F.
Supp. 2d 1, 17 (D.D.C. 2007) (‘‘the court should be
concerned with any allegations that the proposed
settlement will injure a third party’’).
PO 00000
Frm 00117
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
relief from FERC because, in early 2008,
well before DOJ brought its civil
antitrust action against KeySpan,
FERC’s Staff concluded there was no
evidence that KeySpan’s bidding
behavior violated FERC’s AntiManipulation Rule, 18 C.F.R. § 1c2(a).
FERC Docket Nos. IN08–2–000 & EL07–
39–000, Enforcement Staff Report,
Findings of a Non-Public Investigation
of Potential Market Manipulation by
Suppliers in the New York City
Capacity Market, p. 17 (February 28,
2008). Thus, in this case ratepayers
harmed by KeySpan’s anti-competitive
conduct may have no meaningful
recourse under either the antitrust law
or the Federal Power Act.
Even if DOJ could not recover
damages under the Sherman Antitrust
Act for harm suffered by ratepayers, and
is limited to Morgan Stanley’s $21.6
million total net revenues, the Court
should, when weighing the
reasonableness of settling for roughly 20
cents on the dollar, consider the larger
consumer harm Morgan Stanley caused,
and the apparent lack of any other
effective remedy for consumers that
were harmed. This lack of a remedy for
customers is highly significant given the
potential size of the consumer harm
Morgan Stanley caused by violating the
antitrust law. Yet DOJ has not offered
any evidence of how much Morgan
Stanley’s alleged illegal conduct
increased electricity capacity market
prices.
If Morgan Stanley’s illegal conduct
harmed consumers by preventing price
declines that could have totaled tens of
millions of dollars, then the proposed
$4.8 million settlement is so low it
would not be fair, reasonable, adequate
or in the public interest. Cf. S.E.C. v.
Bank Of America Corp., 653 F. Supp.2d
507 (S.D.N.Y. 2009) (disapproving a
proposed settlement in part because the
proposed $33 million fine was ‘‘a trivial
penalty for a false statement that
materially infected a multi-billion-dollar
merger’’). But 4: S.E.C. v. Bank Of
America Corp., llll F.
Supp.2dllll, 2010 U.S. Dist. LEXIS
15460 (S.D.N.Y. Feb. 22, 2010)
(approving a $150 million fine even
though it would have only ‘‘a very
modest impact on corporate practices or
victim compensation’’).
Accordingly, the Court should direct
DOJ to address this defect in the
settlement proposal. Although
exactitude is not required, some
evidence should be proffered on this
point. See New York v. Julius Nasso
Concrete corp., 202 F.3d 82, 88–89 (2d
Cir. 2000) (‘‘Where * * * there is a
dearth of market information unaffected
by the collusive action of the
E:\FR\FM\14MRN1.SGM
14MRN1
Federal Register / Vol. 77, No. 50 / Wednesday, March 14, 2012 / Notices
defendants, the plaintiff’s burden of
proving damages, is, to an extent,
lightened[,] [and] the State need only
provide the court with some relevant
data from which the district court can
make a reasonable estimated calculation
of the harm suffered.* * *’’) (citations
and internal quotations omitted); id, 202
F.3d at 89 rino do otherwise would be
a perversion of fundamental principles
of justice [and would] deny all relief to
the injured person, and thereby relieve
the wrongdoer from making any amends
for his acts’’); New York v. Hendrickson
Bros., Inc., 840 F.2d 1065, 1078 (2d Cir.
1988) (‘‘The most elementary
conceptions of justice and public policy
require that the wrongdoer shall bear
the risk of the uncertainty which his
own wrong has created’) (quoting
Bigelow v. RKO Radio Pictures, Inc.,
327 U.S. 251, 264 (1946)); Fishman v.
Estate of Wirtz, 807 F.2d 520, 551 (7th
Cir. Ill. 1986) (‘‘The concept of a
‘yardstick’ measure of damages, that is,
linking the plaintiffs experience in a
hypothetical free market to the
experience of a comparable firm in an
actual free market, is also well
accepted’’).
CONCLUSION
For the reasons stated above, the
Court should direct DOJ to supplement
the record to demonstrate why this
settlement will prevent such violations
in the future.
Respectfully submitted,
Peter McGowan
General Counsel
By: Sean Mullany, Assistant Counsel Of
Counsel, Public Service Commission,
Of the State of New York, Three
Empire State Plaza, Albany, New York
12223–1350.
Dated: December 30, 2011, Albany, New
York
[FR Doc. 2012–5952 Filed 3–13–12; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE M
NATIONAL SCIENCE FOUNDATION
Agency Information Collection
Activities: Comment Request; Generic
Survey Clearance for the Directorate of
Education and Human Resources
(EHR)
National Science Foundation.
Notice.
srobinson on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
AGENCY:
ACTION:
The National Science
Foundation (NSF) is announcing plans
to request renewed clearance of this
collection. In accordance with the
requirement of section 3506(c)(2)(A) of
the Paperwork Reduction Act of 1995,
SUMMARY:
VerDate Mar<15>2010
19:41 Mar 13, 2012
Jkt 226001
we are providing opportunity for public
comment on this action. After obtaining
and considering public comment, NSF
will prepare the submission requesting
Office of Management and Budget
(OMB) clearance of this collection for no
longer than 3 years.
Comments are invited on: (a) Whether
the proposed collection of information
is necessary for the proper performance
of the functions of the Agency,
including whether the information shall
have practical utility; (b) the accuracy of
the Agency’s estimate of the burden of
the proposed collection of information;
(c) ways to enhance the quality, utility,
and clarity of the information on
respondents, including through the use
of automated collection techniques or
other forms of information technology;
and (d) ways to minimize the burden of
the collection of information on
respondents, including through the use
of automated collection techniques or
other forms of information technology.
DATES: Written comments should be
received by May 14, 2012 to be assured
of consideration. Comments received
after that date will be considered to the
extent practicable.
ADDRESSES: Written comments
regarding the information collection and
requests for copies of the proposed
information collection request should be
addressed to Suzanne Plimpton, Reports
Clearance Officer, National Science
Foundation, 4201 Wilson Blvd., Rm.
295, Arlington, VA 22030, or by email
to splimpto@nsf.gov.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
Suzanne Plimpton on (703) 292–7556 or
send email to splimpto@nsf.gov.
Individuals who use a
telecommunications device for the deaf
(TDD) may call the Federal Information
Relay Service (FIRS) at 1–800–877–8339
between 8 a.m. and 8 p.m., Eastern time,
Monday through Friday.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION:
Title of Collection: EHR Generic
Clearance.
OMB Approval Number: 3145–0136.
Expiration Date of Approval: July 31,
2012.
Abstract: The National Science
Foundation (NSF) requests renewal of
program accountability and
communication data collections (e.g.,
surveys, face-to-face and telephone
interviews, observations, and focus
groups) that describe and track the
impact of NSF funding that focuses on
the Nation’s science, technology,
engineering, and mathematics (STEM)
education and STEM workforce. NSF
funds grants, contracts, and cooperative
agreements to colleges, universities, and
other eligible institutions, and provides
PO 00000
Frm 00118
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
15139
graduate research fellowships to
individuals in all parts of the United
States and internationally.
The Directorate for Education and
Human Resources (EHR), a unit within
NSF, promotes rigor and vitality within
the Nation’s STEM education enterprise
to further the development of the 21st
century’s STEM workforce and public
scientific literacy. EHR does this
through diverse projects and programs
that support research, extension,
outreach, and hands-on activities that
service STEM learning and research at
all institutional (e.g., pre-school through
postdoctoral) levels in formal and
informal settings; and individuals of all
ages (birth and beyond). EHR also
focuses on broadening participation in
STEM learning and careers among
United States citizens, permanent
residents, and nationals, particularly
those individuals traditionally
underemployed in the STEM research
workforce, including but not limited to
women, persons with disabilities, and
racial and ethnic minorities.
At the request of OMB an EHR
Generic Clearance was established in
1995 to integrate management,
monitoring, and evaluation information
pertaining to the NSF’s Education and
Training (ET) portfolio in response to
the Government Performance and
Results Acts (GPRA) of 1993. Under this
generic survey clearance (OMB 3145–
0136), data from the NSF administrative
databases are incorporated with findings
gathered through initiative-, divisional, and program-specific data collections.
The scope of the EHR Generic Clearance
primarily covers descriptive information
gathered from education and training
projects that are funded by NSF. Most
programs subject to EHR Generic data
collection are funded by the EHR
Directorate, but some are funded in
whole or in part by disciplinary
directorates or multi-disciplinary or
cross-cutting programs. Since 2001 in
accordance with OMB’s Terms of
Clearance (TOC), NSF primarily uses
the data from the EHR Generic
Clearance for program planning,
management, and audit purposes to
respond to queries from the Congress,
the public, NSF’s external merit
reviewers who serve as advisors,
including Committees of Visitors
(COVs), and the NSF’s Office of the
Inspector General.
OMB has limited the collection to
three categories of descriptive data: (1)
Staff and project participants (data that
are also necessary to determine
individual-level treatment and control
groups for future third-party study); (2)
project implementation characteristics
(also necessary for future use to identify
E:\FR\FM\14MRN1.SGM
14MRN1
Agencies
[Federal Register Volume 77, Number 50 (Wednesday, March 14, 2012)]
[Notices]
[Pages 15125-15139]
From the Federal Register Online via the Government Printing Office [www.gpo.gov]
[FR Doc No: 2012-5952]
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE
Antitrust Division
United States v. Morgan Stanley; Public Comments and Response on
Proposed Final Judgment
Pursuant to the Antitrust Procedures and Penalties Act, 15 U.S.C.
16(b)-(h), the United States hereby publishes below the comments
received on the proposed Final Judgment in United States v. Morgan
Stanley, Civil Action No. 1:11-CV-06875-WHP, which were filed in the
United States District Court for the Southern District of New York on
March 6, 2012, together with the response of the United States to the
comments.
Copies of the comments and the response are available for
inspection at the Department of Justice Antitrust Division, 450 Fifth
Street, NW., Suite 1010, Washington, DC 20530 (telephone: 202-514-
2481), on the Department of Justice's Web site at https://www.justice.gov/atr, and at the Office of the Clerk of the United
States District Court for the Southern District of New York, 500 Pearl
Street, New York, New York 10007. Copies of any of these materials may
be obtained upon request and payment of a copying fee.
Patricia A. Brink,
Director of Civil Enforcement.
IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE SOUTHERN DISTRICT OF NEW
YORK
UNITED STATES OF AMERICA, Plaintiff, v. MORGAN STANLEY, Defendant.
Civil Action No.: 11-civ-6875 WHP
Hon. William Pauley III
RESPONSE OF PLAINTIFF UNITED STATES TO PUBLIC COMMENTS ON THE PROPOSED
FINAL JUDGMENT
Pursuant to the requirements of the Antitrust Procedures and
Penalties Act, 15 U.S.C. Sec. 16(b)-(h) (``Tunney Act''), the United
States files the public comments concerning the proposed Final Judgment
in this case and the United States' response to those comments. After
careful consideration, the United States continues to believe that the
relief sought in the proposed Final Judgment will provide an effective
and appropriate remedy for the antitrust violation alleged in the
Complaint. The United States will move the Court for entry of the
proposed Final Judgment after the public comments and this Response
have been published in the Federal Register, pursuant to 15 U.S.C.
Sec. 16(d).
[[Page 15126]]
I. PROCEDURAL HISTORY
The United States brought this lawsuit against Defendant Morgan
Stanley on September 30, 2011, to remedy a violation of Section 1 of
the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. Sec. 1. In January 2006, Morgan Stanley
Capital Group Inc. (``MSCG''), a subsidiary of defendant Morgan
Stanley,\1\ executed agreements with KeySpan Corporation (``KeySpan'')
and Astoria Generating Company Acquisitions, L.L.C. (``Astoria'') that
would effectively combine the economic interests of the two largest
competitors in the New York City electric capacity market. The likely
effect of this combination was to increase capacity prices for the
retail electricity suppliers who must purchase capacity, and, in turn,
to increase the prices consumers pay for electricity.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1\ MSCG and Morgan Stanley are collectively referred to
hereinafter as ``Morgan.''
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Simultaneously with the filing of the Complaint, the United States
filed a proposed Final Judgment and a Stipulation signed by the United
States and Morgan consenting to the entry of the proposed Final
Judgment after compliance with the requirements of the Tunney Act.
Pursuant to those requirements, the United States filed a Competitive
Impact Statement (``CIS'') in this Court on September 30, 2011;
published the proposed Final Judgment and CIS in the Federal Register
on October 11, 2011, see United States v. Morgan Stanley, Proposed
Final Judgment and Competitive Impact Statement, 76 Fed. Reg. 62843
(Oct. 11, 2011); and published summaries of the terms of the proposed
Final Judgment and CIS, together with directions for the submission of
written comments relating to the proposed Final Judgment (``PFJ''), in
The Washington Times for seven days (October 10 through October 14 and
October 17 and 18, 2011) and in The New York Post for seven days
(October 25 through October 31, 2011). The 60-day period for public
comments ended on December 30, 2011. The United States received two
comments, as described below, which are attached hereto.
II. THE COMPLAINT AND THE PROPOSED FINAL JUDGMENT
A. Background
As alleged in the Complaint and as discussed more fully in the CIS
[Dkt. 2] at 2-7, this case involves Morgan's participation in
an agreement with KeySpan that caused an anticompetitive effect in the
New York City Capacity Market.\2\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\2\ In the state of New York, sellers of retail electricity must
purchase a product from generators known as installed capacity
(``capacity'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
In 2005, KeySpan, a pivotal capacity supplier, anticipated that
tight supply and demand conditions in the New York City capacity market
would ease due to entry of new generation. Concerned that market entry
would lead to lower prices and revenues, KeySpan studied various
options, including the direct purchase of Astoria. Such an acquisition,
however, would have raised significant market power concerns. KeySpan
decided instead to approach Morgan to arrange a financial transaction
that would provide KeySpan an indirect financial interest in Astoria's
capacity sales. Morgan informed KeySpan that such an agreement between
Morgan and KeySpan would be contingent on Morgan also entering into an
agreement with Astoria, the only other generator with sufficient
capacity to offset Morgan's payments to KeySpan.
In January 2006, Morgan entered into a financial derivative
agreement with KeySpan (the ``Morgan/KeySpan Swap''), and, at the same
time, an offsetting agreement with Astoria (the ``Morgan/Astoria
Hedge''). Under the terms of the Morgan/KeySpan Swap, when the market
clearing price for capacity was above a certain amount, Morgan
essentially was required to pay KeySpan a multiple of the difference
between the clearing price and the strike price.\3\ The terms of both
the Morgan/KeySpan Swap and the Morgan/Astoria Hedge ran from May 2006
through April 2009. Morgan earned approximately $21.6 million in net
revenues from the two agreements.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\3\ Under the Morgan/KeySpan Swap, if the market price for
capacity was above the strike price ($7.57 per kW-month), Morgan
would pay KeySpan the difference between the market price and $7.57
times 1800 MW; if the market price was below $7.57, KeySpan would
pay Morgan the difference times 1800 MW. Under the Morgan/Astoria
Hedge, if the market price for capacity was above $7.07 per kW-
month, Astoria would pay Morgan the difference times 1800 MW; if the
market price was below $7.07, Astoria would be paid the difference
times 1800 MW. Morgan retained the differential (e.g., $7.57-$7.07
times 1800 MW) as revenues.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The revenues from Astoria's capacity sales that KeySpan obtained
through the Morgan/KeySpan Swap effectively eliminated KeySpan's
incentive to compete for sales in the same way a purchase of Astoria or
a direct agreement between KeySpan and Astoria would have done. As a
result, KeySpan consistently bid its capacity into the capacity
auctions at the highest allowed price and, despite the addition of
significant new generating capacity in New York City, the market price
of capacity did not decline.\4\ This result would not have been
achieved without Morgan's participation.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\4\ The effects of the Morgan/KeySpan Swap continued until March
2008, at which time changes in regulatory conditions eliminated
KeySpan's ability to affect the market price. KeySpan was sold to
another company in August 2007. The State of New York conditioned
its approval of the acquisition on the divestiture of KeySpan's
Ravenswood generating assets and required KeySpan to bid its New
York capacity at zero from March 2008 until the divestiture was
completed. Since then, the market price for capacity has declined.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
B. United States v. KeySpan
On February 22, 2010, the United States filed suit against KeySpan
for its role in the Morgan/KeySpan Swap. Simultaneous with the filing
of its Complaint, the United States filed a proposed Final Judgment
requiring KeySpan to pay to the United States $12 million as
disgorgement of ill-gotten gains. See Complaint, United States v.
KeySpan Corp., No. 10-1415 (S.D.N.Y. Feb. 22, 2010). On February 2,
2011, after completion of the Tunney Act procedures, the Court entered
the KeySpan Final Judgment, and, in making its public interest
determination, found that disgorgement is available to remedy
violations of the Sherman Act. See United States v. KeySpan Corp., 763
F. Supp. 2d 633, 638-41 (S.D.N.Y. 2011) (WHP).
C. The Morgan Complaint and Proposed Final Judgment
On September 30, 2011, the United States filed the current suit
against Morgan for its role in the Morgan/KeySpan Swap. The United
States alleges that Morgan entered into an agreement (the Morgan/
KeySpan Swap), the likely effect of which was to increase prices in the
New York City Capacity Market, in violation of Section 1 of the Sherman
Act, 15 U.S.C. Sec. 1. Simultaneous with the filing of its Complaint,
the United States filed a proposed Final Judgment requiring Morgan to
pay to the Treasury of the United States $4.8 million as disgorgement
of ill-gotten gains. The proposed Final Judgment requires Morgan to
disgorge profits gained as a result of its unlawful agreement in
restraint of trade. As stated in the CIS, the proposed relief serves
the public interest by depriving Morgan of ill-gotten gains, thereby
deterring Morgan and others from engaging in similar anticompetitive
conduct in the future.
[[Page 15127]]
II. STANDARDS GOVERNING THE COURT'S PUBLIC INTEREST DETERMINATION UNDER
THE TUNNEY ACT
The Tunney Act calls for the Court, in making its public interest
determination, to consider certain factors relating to the competitive
impact of the judgment and whether it adequately remedies the harm
alleged in the complaint. See 15 U.S.C. Sec. 16(e)(1)(A) and (B)
(listing factors to be considered).
This public interest inquiry is necessarily a limited one, as the
United States is entitled to deference in crafting its antitrust
settlements, especially with respect to the scope of its complaint and
the adequacy of its remedy. See generally United States v. Microsoft
Corp., 56 F.3d 1448, 1458-62 (DC Cir. 1995); United States v. SBC
Commc'ns, 489 F. Supp. 2d 1, 12-17 (D.D.C. 2007). Under the Tunney Act,
the ``Court's function is not to determine whether the proposed
[d]ecree results in the balance of rights and liabilities that is the
one that will best serve society, but only to ensure that the resulting
settlement is within the reaches of the public interest.'' KeySpan, 763
F. Supp. 2d at 637 (quoting United States v. Alex Brown & Sons, 963 F.
Supp. 235, 238 (S.D.N.Y. 1997) (quoting Microsoft, 56 F.3d at 1460)
(emphasis in original), aff'd sub nom, United States v. Bleznak, 153
F.3d 16 (2d Cir. 1998)).
With respect to the scope of the complaint, the Tunney Act review
does not provide for an examination of possible competitive harms the
United States did not allege. See, e.g., Microsoft, 56 F.3d at 1459
(holding that it is improper to reach beyond the complaint to evaluate
claims that the government did not make).
With respect to the sufficiency of the proposed remedy, the United
States is entitled to deference as to its views of the nature of the
case, its perception of the market structure, and its predictions as to
the effect of proposed remedies. See, e.g., KeySpan, 763 F. Supp. 2d at
642; SBC Commc'ns, 489 F. Supp. 2d at 17 (holding that the United
States is entitled to deference as to predictions about the efficacy of
its remedies). Under this standard, the United States need not show
that a settlement will perfectly remedy the alleged antitrust harm;
rather, it need only provide a factual basis for concluding that the
settlement is a reasonably adequate remedy for the alleged harm. SBC
Commc'ns, 489 F. Supp. 2d at 17. A court should not reject the United
States' proposed remedies merely because other remedies may be
preferable. KeySpan, 763 F. Supp. 2d at 637-38.
III. SUMMARY OF COMMENTS
The United States received formal comments from the Public Service
Commission of the State of New York (``PSC'') and from AARP, a
nonprofit organization that helps people over the age of fifty.\5\ At
the outset, both comments commend the United States for enforcing the
antitrust laws to protect the integrity of New York capacity markets.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\5\ On January 13, 2012, State Senator Michael Gianaris and New
York City Council Member Peter Vallone sent a joint letter to the
Court asking the Court to re-evaluate the proposed settlement. The
letter was placed in the case docket [Dkt. 9]. The letter
raises issues similar to those raised by the PSC and AARP;
accordingly, these issues will be fully addressed in this response
of the United States to the formal comments submitted by the PSC and
AARP.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The comments raise three central objections: (1) that the proposed
$4.8 million dollar disgorgement is inadequate to deter similar
anticompetitive conduct or otherwise serve its remedial purpose,
especially given the likely magnitude of the injury to consumers from
any increase in New York City capacity prices (PSC Cmts at 7-14; AARP
Cmts at 11-16 and 19-25); (2) that the decree does not contain an
admission of wrongdoing by Morgan (AARP Cmts at 16-18); and (3) that
the disgorged proceeds, rather than being remitted to the Treasury,
should directly or indirectly benefit electricity consumers who paid
higher electricity rates as a result of the illegal agreement (AARP
Cmts at 10-16).
AARP recommends that the United States withdraw from the proposed
settlement and proceed in the litigation or renegotiate a settlement
with Morgan that would provide equitable relief to electric utility
customers, an admission by Morgan of its violation of the Sherman Act,
a quantification of the total harm to consumers, and a disgorgement of
all profits Morgan realized from the transaction at issue. AARP Cmts at
28. The PSC asks the Court to order the United States to supplement the
record. PSC Cmts at 16.
IV. RESPONSE TO THE COMMENTS
The United States has carefully considered these objections but
finds that they do not warrant modification of the proposed Final
Judgment.
A. The Proposed Remedy Is Appropriate and Deters Anticompetitive
Conduct
The commenters argue that disgorgement of $4.8 million is an
inadequate remedy that will not serve as an effective deterrent,
especially when compared to Morgan's approximately $21.6 million net
revenues earned under the Swap and the increased prices paid by
electricity consumers. Such concerns are misplaced.\6\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\6\ AARP requests access to the derivative agreements. AARP Cmts
at 21. The agreement that the United States alleged violated the
Sherman Act--the Morgan/KeySpan Swap--is publicly available as an
attachment to KeySpan's January 18, 2006 Form 8-K filing with the
SEC in which KeySpan announced that it had entered into the
transaction, available at https://www.sec.gov/Archivesiedgar/data/10623791000106237906000004/ex101-8kjan2406.txt.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The proposed remedy constitutes significant and meaningful relief.
In its action against KeySpan, the United States sought disgorgement
under the Sherman Act for the first time. In approving that settlement,
this Court recognized that the disgorgement by a power generator
engaged in an alleged anticompetitive scheme would become ``an
important marker for enforcement agencies and utility regulators
alike.'' KeySpan, 763 F. Supp. 2d at 642. In this case, the United
States seeks disgorgement from the financial services firm that
facilitated the transaction. Just as the KeySpan remedy created an
important marker for disgorgement from the principal competitor in an
anticompetitive scheme, the proposed remedy in this unprecedented case
demonstrates the United States' resolve to pursue financial services
firms that leverage derivative agreements for anticompetitive ends, and
the antitrust liability that may result from such enforcement actions.
Financial services firms contemplating the use of such anticompetitive
agreements will now recognize the prospect of Sherman Act liability and
disgorgement, thereby diminishing their appetite for and deterring this
illegal conduct. Indeed, the filing of the proposed settlement has
already prompted legal commentators to warn about the enforcement
issues raised by this case, including the duty of financial services
firms to consider the implications of their agreements on competition
in the underlying markets.\7\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\7\ See, e.g., Mary Arm Mason & William Monts III, Morgan
Stanley to Disgorge Profits Earned from Anticompetitive Derivative
Agreements, Hogan Lovells (Dec. 9, 2011) (reporting that ``[Ole key
points from the Morgan Stanley case for financial services clients
are: (1) the DOJ is prepared to use Section 1 to outlaw financial
arrangements aimed at producing anticompetitive effects, (2) the DOJ
will take enforcement action against the financial services
companies that facilitate these arrangements, even though they do
not participate in the underlying physical commodity market, and (3)
pure financial players may have a duty to examine the competitive
effects of their arrangements on the underlying markets''),
available at https://emailcc.com/rv/ff000213bdac60e42b089aa3f84a8b12fdc2a196; Barry Nigro & Maria
Cirincione, DOJ Orders Financial Services Firm to Disgorge Profits
from Derivative Contract, Fried Frank Antitrust & Comp. L. (Oct. 17,
2011) (reporting that this case ``puts firms on notice that any type
of agreement facilitating anticompetitive conduct is subject to
scrutiny and that the DOJ may seek penalties against indirect third
party participants, as well as direct competitors''), available at
https://www.friedfrank.com/siteFiles/Publications/Final%2010-17-11%20D0J%200rders%20Financial%20Services%20Firm%20to%20Disgorge%20Profits%20from%20Derivative%20Contract.pdf.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
[[Page 15128]]
The PSC and AARP nevertheless argue that disgorgement of anything
short of the $21.6 million in net revenues earned by Morgan under the
Swap \8\ will not strip Morgan of the entirety of its ill-gotten gains
and therefore will not deter the conduct at issue. This position
ignores the deterrent value of the proposed settlement described above.
It also ignores the disputes that would likely arise in calculating
Morgan's ill-gotten gains for the purpose of determining disgorgement.
The theory of the United States' case rests on the illegality of the
Morgan/KeySpan Swap but not the Astoria Hedge. As such, were this
matter to proceed to trial, Morgan would likely contend that but for
the Morgan/KeySpan Swap, it would have entered into a legitimate
transaction with someone other than KeySpan to offset the Astoria
Hedge, and that any disgorgement remedy should be adjusted downward to
account for a legitimate retum.\9\ Although the United States would
have contested these arguments and sought disgorgement of the full
$21.6 million in net revenues had this action proceeded to trial, the
settlement reflects, among other things, the fact that there is a
dispute about the amount of Morgan's net revenues that were ill-gotten.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\8\ There is no dispute that Morgan earned $21.6 million under
the two derivative agreements.
\9\ Though a legitimate off-setting counter-party would likely
not have agreed to the strike price as high as the $7.57 per kW-
month found in the Morgan/KeySpan Swap, Morgan would nonetheless
have earned revenues from a legitimate off-setting transaction so
long as it exceeded the $7.07 per KW-month price in the Astoria
Hedge. In the alternative, Morgan would also dispute that the entire
$21.6 million earned under both agreements is cognizable as ill-
gotten gains. See CIS at note 4.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The United States recognizes that it has not proved its case at
trial and that ``a court considering a proposed settlement does not
have actual findings that the defendant[] engaged in illegal practices,
as would exist after a trial.'' SBC Commc'ns, 489 F. Supp. 2d at 15
(citing Microsoft, 56 F.3d at 1461). The $4.8 million disgorgement
amount is the product of settlement negotiations and accounts for
litigation risks and costs. It is appropriate to consider litigation
risk and the context of a settlement when evaluating whether a proposed
remedy is in the public interest.\10\ As this Court has recognized
``Mlle adequacy of the disgorgement amount must be evaluated in view of
the Government's decision to settle its claims and seek entry of the
consent decree. When a litigant chooses to forgo discovery and trial in
favor of settlement, full damages cannot be expected.'' \11\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\10\ Indeed, ``room must be made for the government to grant
concessions in the negotiation process for settlements.'' SBC, 489
F. Supp. 2d at 15.
\11\ KeySpan, 763 F. Supp. 2d at 642 (citing In re Linerboard
Antitrust Litig., 321 F. Supp. 2d 619, 633 (E.D. Pa 2004)
(collecting cases) & In re Milken & Assocs. Sec Litig., 150 F.R.D.
46, 54 (S.D.N.Y 1993) (``The Second Circuit has held that a
settlement can be approved even though the benefits amount to a
small percentage of the recovery sought.'')).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Here, the litigation costs and risks are not insignificant. The
United States would have had to establish at trial that the KeySpan
Swap caused anticompetitive effects in the New York capacity market, a
complex endeavor that would have required substantial fact and expert
testimony and evidence. And, in the present case against Morgan
Stanley, the United States would have had the additional burden of
establishing the liability of a financial services firm for using a
derivative agreement to facilitate an anticompetitive effect even
though the company itself was not a participant in the underlying
market. Assuming the United States prevailed on liability, there would
be additional risk, as discussed above, in establishing the proper
disgorgement amount. While the United States is confident that it could
prevail on these issues at trial, the settlement obviates the risk--and
significant cost--of litigation.
The PSC and AARP also argue that the reasonableness of the proposed
remedy should be evaluated in light of the ratepayer harm caused by
Morgan. PSC Cmts at 13-15; AARP Cmts at 5, 11, 16. In essence, they
seek a disgorgement amount that takes into account the losses suffered
by retail electricity consumers. As this Court recognized in KeySpan,
such comments ``fail to comprehend the nature of the disgorgement
remedy. The 'primary purpose of disgorgement is not to compensate
investors,' but rather to divest a wrongdoer of the proceeds of their
misconduct.'' KeySpan, 763 F. Supp. 2d at 642 (quoting SEC v.
Cavanaugh, 445 F. 3d 105, 117 (2d Cir. 2006)). Indeed, the extent of
market harm is not relevant to the disgorgement calculation; once a
violation has been established, a district court ``possesses the
equitable power to grant disgorgement without inquiring whether, or to
what extent, identifiable private parties have been damaged by [the
violation].'' \12\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\12\ SEC v. Blavin, 760 F.2d 706, 713 (6th Cir. 1985). See also
SEC v. Tome, 833 F.2d 1086, 1096 (2d Cir. 1987) (``Whether or not
[any victims] may be entitled to money damages is immaterial [to
disgorgement].'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
In this case, the source of Morgan's ill-gotten gains is the
revenues it earned under the derivative agreements. Indeed, the
derivative agreements represent Morgan's only source of revenue in this
case. Morgan did not participate in the actual capacity market and thus
it did not earn any auction revenues, much less pocket consumer
overpayments. Moreover, as the United States explained in the KeySpan
proceedings,\13\ an inquiry into consumer harm would require the Court
to assess the price of capacity that would have prevailed absent the
Swap, a problematic exercise given the uncertainty of determining
market outcomes absent the Swap. Accordingly, given the difficulty of
definitively estimating the harm to the market and its irrelevance to
the questions relating to the adequacy of the disgorgement remedy,
AARP's assertion that the United States is obligated to provide
estimates of total economic harm and profits received by all market
participants resulting from the alleged violation should be rejected.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\13\ See October 12, 2010 Transcript of Hearing in United States
v. KeySpan, 1:10-cv-01415-WHP, at 10-14. In addition, in this case
as in KeySpan, commenters' estimates of consumer harm may be
significantly overstated. Id. at 14-15.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
B. Public Policy Rejects the Contention That a Settlement of a
Government Antitrust Case Should Contain an Admission of Wrongdoing
AARP argues that the proposed final judgment is not in the public
interest because it does not contain an admission or finding that
Morgan violated the law. Similarly, the PSC quotes language from SEC v.
Citigroup challenging the sufficiency of a consent judgment ``that does
not involve any admissions'' by the defendant.\14\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\14\ AARP Cmts at 16-18 & 28 (recommending that the PFJ be
amended to include an ``admission by Morgan of its violation''); PSC
Cmts at 10 (quoting SEC v. Citigroup Global Markets, Inc., Slip Op.
at 10, 2011 WL 5903733 at *5 (S.D.N.Y. 2011)).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Government antitrust suits are governed by a specialized statutory
regime that provides no basis to require that consent decrees include
either a finding or an admission of liability.\15\ Congress has
designed the remedial
[[Page 15129]]
provisions of the antitrust laws to encourage consent judgments, which
allow the government to obtain relief without the ``time, expense and
inevitable risk of litigation.'' United States v. Armour and Co., 402
U.S. 673, 681 (1971). Thus, for nearly a century, the antitrust laws
have expressly limited the ability of private plaintiffs seeking treble
damages to rely on consent decrees entered in government cases. Section
5 of the Clayton Act, originally enacted in 1914,\16\ provides that
litigated final judgments establishing a violation in civil or criminal
cases ``brought by or on behalf of the United States under the
antitrust laws'' shall be ``prima facie evidence'' against the
defendant in subsequent private litigation, but the statute specifies
that this provision does not apply to ``consent judgments or decrees
entered before any testimony has been taken.'' 15 U.S.C. Sec. 16(a).
Under this regime, a defendant can elect to accept a consent decree and
avoid the risk of a litigated judgment that would seriously weaken its
position in follow-on private litigation. Congress provided this
exception to the Clayton Act's prima facie evidence provision ``in
order to encourage defendants to settle promptly government-initiated
antitrust claims and thereby to save the government the time and
expense of further litigation.'' United States v. National Ass'n of
Broadcasters, 553 F. Supp. 621, 623 (D.D.C. 1982) (collecting cases).
Requiring admissions or findings of liability as a prerequisite to
entering a consent decree would undercut Congress's purpose and
contravene the public interest in allowing the government to obtain
relief without the risk and delay of litigation.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\15\ The district court proceedings in the Citigroup case have
been temporarily stayed by the Court of Appeals (pending a panel
ruling on a motion to stay pending appeal). SEC v. Citigroup Global
Markets Inc., 2011 WL 6937373 (2nd Cir. Dec. 27, 2011).
\16\ 63 Cong. Ch. 323, 38 Stat. 730, 731, codified as amended at
15 U.S.C. Sec. 16(a).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Congress confirmed its continuing recognition of the importance of
consent decrees when it amended the Clayton Act in 1974 to specify
procedural requirements governing a district court's determination of
whether entry of a proposed consent decree in a government antitrust
case is in the public interest. Antitrust Procedures and Penalties Act,
Sec. 2, Pub. L. No. 93-528, 88 Stat 1706 (1974), codified at 15 U.S.C.
Sec. 16(b)-(h) (``Tunney Act''). The repeated references to the
``alleged'' violation in the language of the Tunney Act strongly
suggest that Congress did not expect decrees arising under the
antitrust laws to contain admissions of liability.\17\ And the
legislative history unambiguously demonstrates Congress' understanding
that government antitrust settlements typically occur without an
admission or finding of liability. The Senate Report accompanying S.
782, the bill that became the Tunney Act, explains:
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\17\ With one exception, every reference to ``violation'' or
``violations'' in the Tunney Act is immediately preceded by
``alleged.'' The only exception is a reference to ``the violations
set forth in the complaint.'' 15 U.S.C. Sec. 16(e)(2) as enacted,
currently 16 U.S.C. Sec. 16(e)(1)(B). The Tunney Act contains no
reference to admissions or findings of violations or of liability.
Congress amended the Tunney Act in 2004, but those amendments do not
affect the analysis here.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The entry of a consent decree is a judicial act which requires the
approval of a United States district court. Once entered the consent
decree represents a contract between the government and the respondent
upon which the parties agree to terminate the litigation. Pursuant to
the terms of the decree, the defendant agrees to abide by certain
conditions in the future. However the defendant does not admit to
having violated the law as alleged in the complaint. Obviously, the
consent decree is of crucial importance as an enforcement tool, since
it permits the allocation of resources elsewhere.\18\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\18\ S. Rep. No. 298, 93d Cong., 1st Sess. (1973) (``S. Rep.'')
at 5 (emphasis added). See also 119 Cong. Rec. 3449, 3451 (Feb. 6,
1973 floor statement of Senator Tunney: ``Essentially the decree is
a device by which the defendant, while refusing to admit guilt,
agrees to modify its conduct and in some cases to accept certain
remedies designed to correct the violation asserted by the
Government.''). (The legislative history of the Tunney Act,
including the House and Senate Reports and the statement of Senator
Tunney cited herein, is available at https://www.justice.gov/jmd/ls/legislative_histories/pl93-528/pl93-528.html).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The corresponding House Report is equally clear on the point:
``Ordinarily, defendants do not admit to having violated the antitrust
or other laws alleged as violated in complaints that are settled.''
\19\ Moreover, both reports plainly reveal that Congress not only
understood the practice of entering into such consent decrees, but
encouraged it, considering them a ``legitimate and integral part of
antitrust enforcement'' and urging that they be retained ``as a
substantial antitrust enforcement tool.'' \20\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\19\ H. Rep. No. 1463, 93rd Cong., 2d Sess. (1974) (``H. Rep.'')
at 6, reprinted at 1974 U.S. Code Cong. & Admin. News 6535, 6536-37.
See also id. (``Present law, 15 U.S.C. Sec. 16(a), encourages
settlement by consent decree as part of the legal policies expressed
in the antitrust laws. * * * The bill preserves these legal and
enforcement policies. * * *'').
\20\ S. Rep. at 3 & 7; see also H. Rep. at 8, 1974 U.S.C.C.A.N.
at 6539 (also describing consent decrees as a ``viable settlement
option'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Accordingly, the government routinely enters into antitrust consent
decrees explicitly disclaiming admissions or findings of liability.\21\
The Supreme Court has long endorsed the entry of consent judgments in
which there is no finding of liability,\22\ and it has done so even
when the defendant has affirmatively denied the alleged violation.\23\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\21\ The proposed Final Judgment in this case states that the
United States and defendant Morgan have ``consented to the entry of
this Final Judgment without trial or adjudication of any issue of
fact or law, for settlement purposes only, and without this Final
Judgment constituting any evidence against or an admission by Morgan
for any purpose with respect to any claim or allegation contained in
the Complaint.'' PFJ at 1. Equivalent statements are conventional in
government antitrust consent decrees negotiated pre-trial.
\22\ Cf: Armour, 402 U.S. at 681 (interpreting consent decree in
which defendants had denied liability for the allegations raised in
the complaint); see also 18A Wright and Miller, Federal Practice and
Procedure Sec. 4443, at 256-57 (2d ed. 2002) (``central
characteristic of a consent judgment is that the court has not
actually resolved the substance of the issues presented'').
\23\ See Swift & Co. v. United States, 276 U.S. 311, 327 (1928)
(refusing to vacate injunctive relief in consent judgment that
contained recitals in which defendants asserted their innocence).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Following enactment of the Tunney Act, courts have expressly
recognized the Congressional intent to preserve the policy of
encouraging antitrust consent decree expressed in that legislation.\24\
Only once, to our knowledge, has a district court objected to a
proposed consent decree on the basis that a defendant had not admitted
liability or wrongdoing, but this objection was specifically rejected
on appeal. In United States v. Microsoft, the district court refused to
enter the proposed consent decree in part because the defendant denied
``that the conduct charged in the Government's complaint to which it
has consented, violates the antitrust laws.'' \25\ The DC Circuit
reversed, expressly holding ``unjustified'' the district court's
criticism of the defendant ``for declining to admit that the practices
charged in the complaint actually violated the antitrust laws.'' \26\
The Court of Appeals emphasized that the ``important question is
whether [the defendant] will abide by the terms of the consent decree
regardless of whether it is willing to admit wrongdoing.'' \27\ We are
aware of no government antitrust case in which a court refused to enter
a consent decree because a defendant had failed to admit liability.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\24\ E.g., United States v. Alex. Brown & Sons, Inc., 963 F.
Supp. 235, 238-39 (S.D.N.Y. 1997) (``In enacting the Tunney Act,
Congress recognized the high rate of settlement in public antitrust
cases and wished to encourage settlement by consent decrees as part
of the legal policies expressed in the antitrust laws.'') (internal
quotations omitted).
\25\ United States v. Microsoft, 159 F.R.D. 318, 337 (D.D.C.
1995), rev 'd 56 F.3d 1448 (D.C. Cir. 1995).
\26\ United States v. Microsoft, 56 F.3d at 1448, 1461 (D.C.
Cir. 1995).
\27\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
AARP's contention that absent an admission of wrongdoing or an
[[Page 15130]]
adjudication of the facts entry of the decree would not be in the
public interest is unwarranted. The relief that would be afforded by
the proposed decree is appropriate to the violation alleged. The Tunney
Act and the public interest require no more. To insist on more is to
impose substantial resource costs on government antitrust enforcement;
to risk the possibility of litigation resulting in no relief at all; to
contravene a century of congressional and judicial policy; and to
establish a precedent that could impede enforcement of the antitrust
laws in the future.
C. Disgorgement of Proceeds to the U.S. Treasury Is Appropriate
AARP argues that Morgan's $4.8 million disgorgement payment should
be made to entities other than the U.S. Treasury in order to benefit
the electricity customers in New York City who paid higher prices as a
result of Morgan's conduct. The United States shares AARP's concern for
the New York City ratepayers and, indeed, brought this case and sought
disgorgement in order to deter financial services firms from entering
into financial arrangements that cause anticompetitive effects. The
United States has carefully considered the suggested alternative uses
for the disgorgement proceeds but has determined that payment to the
U.S. Treasury is the most appropriate result in this circumstance.
The alternative distribution plan proposed by AARP seeks, in
effect, to restore funds to ratepayers. As this Court recognized in
KeySpan, 763 F. Supp. 2d at 643. A remedy that seeks to reimburse funds
to New York City ratepayers would raise questions relating to the filed
rate doctrine, which bars remedies (such as damages) that result, in
effect, in payment by customers and receipt by sellers of a rate
different from that on file for the regulated service. See generally
Square D Co. v. Niagara Frontier, 476 U.S. 409, 423 (1986). Indeed, a
lawsuit filed by private plaintiffs seeking damages from KeySpan and
Morgan based on the Swap has been dismissed on the ground that the
action is barred as a matter of law under the filed rate doctrine.\28\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\28\ See Simon v. KeySpan, 785 F. Supp. 2d at 138-39 (dismissing
actions based on filed rate doctrine and other grounds). Plaintiffs
have appealed this decision to the Second Circuit, but a decision
has not yet been rendered.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
In this case, the United States specifically chose to seek
disgorgement, rather than restitution, as a remedy for this violation.
As discussed in the CIS, disgorgement is particularly appropriate on
the facts of this case to fulfill the remedial goals of the Sherman
Act. CIS at 9-10. Disgorgement also provides finality, certainty,
avoidance of transaction costs, and potential to do the most good for
the most people. As in KeySpan, the proposed remedy here is well within
the reaches of the public interest.\29\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\29\ KeySpan, 763 F. Supp. 2d at 643. Moreover, the
Miscellaneous Receipts Act (``MRA'') provides that members of the
Executive Branch (including employees of the Department of Justice)
who receive money for the United States are to remit such funds
directly to the Treasury. 31 U.S.C. Sec. 3302(b) (2006). A purpose
of the statute is to protect Congress' appropriations authority by
ensuring that money collected from various sources cannot be used
for programs not authorized by law. The proposed remedy avoids any
issues of compliance with the MRA.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
VI. CONCLUSION
After careful consideration of the public comments, the United
States remains of the view that the proposed Final Judgment provides an
effective and appropriate remedy for the antitrust violation alleged in
the Complaint and that its entry would therefore be in the public
interest.
The United States is submitting this Response and the public
comments to the Federal Register for publication pursuant to 15 U.S.C.
Sec. 16(d). After publication occurs, the United States will move this
Court to enter the proposed Final Judgment.
Dated: March 6, 2012
Respectfully submitted, /s/ Jade Alice Eaton, jade.eaton@usdoj.gov,
Trial Attorney, U.S. Department of Justice, Antitrust Division,
Transportation, Energy & Agriculture Section, 450 Fifth Street, NW,
Suite 8000, Washington, DC 20004, Telephone: (202) 307-6316, Facsimile:
(202) 307-2784.
AARP COMMENTS IN OPPOSITION TO PROPOSED SETTLEMENT AND IN SUPPORT OF
FURTHER PROCEEDINGS
Preliminary Statement
On September 30, 2011, the United States Department of Justice
Antitrust Division (``DOT'') filed a Complaint commencing this civil
antitrust action against defendant Morgan Stanley. On the same day, DOJ
filed a proposed Final Judgment, agreed to by Morgan Stanley, which
would settle the case subject to court review and approval, along with
a Competition Impact Statement (``CIS'') in support of the proposed
settlement.\1\ A notice inviting public comment \2\ on the proposed
settlement of this action has been issued, as is required by the Tunney
Act.\3\ AARP submits these comments to DOJ in response to the notice.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1\ The court papers are available at https://www.justice.gov/atr/cases/morgan.html.
\2\ 76 Federal Register, No. 196 (Tuesday, October 11, 2011).
\3\ The Antitrust Procedures and Penalties Act (the ``Tunney
Act''), 15 U.S.C. Sec. 16(e)-(f), requires an opportunity for
public comment prior to a court's review of any proposed settlement
between the government and an alleged antitrust law violator.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
AARP is a nonpartisan, nonprofit organization that helps people
over the age of 50 to exercise independence, choice, and control in
ways beneficial to them and to society as a whole.\4\ AARP has millions
of members, including more than 2,500,000 members who reside in New
York state. AARP is greatly concerned about the threats to health and
safety of vulnerable citizens caused by New York's high electricity
costs.\5\ Because the cost of utilities has skyrocketed, many low and
middle-income families and older people must now choose between paying
utility bills and paying for other essentials such as food and
medicine. AARP works to protect consumers from excessive utility rates
and charges.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\4\ For more information about AARP see https://www.aarp.org/.
\5\ New York residential electric rates are the highest in the
continental United States. Energy Information Agency, Electric Power
Monthly for August, 2011, Average Retail Price of Electricity to
Ultimate Customers by End-Use Sector, by State, table 5.6.A, (Nov.
2011). Available at https://www.eia.gov/electricity/monthly/index.cfm.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Many AARP members were adversely affected by the antitrust
violations alleged in this action, which artificially increased prices
in the electric capacity markets of the New York Independent System
Operator (``NYISO''). Although the excessive charges were paid in the
first instance by load-serving utilities such as Con Edison, they were
directly passed on to utility customers. Utility customers had no way
to escape payment of the inflated charges when their monthly electric
bills were adjusted to include the costs.\6\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\6\ ``Every Con Ed customer in the five boroughs overpaid an
average total of at least $40 over two years during a price-fixing
scheme set up by the owners of a giant Queens power plant, the feds
charge in a court case that would let the alleged gougers get away
with most of the gains.'' Bill Sanderson, $157 M Power Abuse, N.Y.
Post, March 9, 2010, available at https://www.nypost.com/f/print/news/local/power_abuse_SgLN9psbhjopRMEGU68fgK.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
As consumers, AARP members depend upon the protection of the
antitrust laws against the unlawful exercise of monopoly or market
power, such as occurred in this case. They must also rely upon the
vigorous enforcement of the antitrust laws by DOJ and the courts.
AARP commends DOJ for challenging Morgan Stanley's use of financial
derivatives to facilitate gaming by
[[Page 15131]]
Keyspan and Astoria in the NYISO electricity auctions. AARP urges,
however, that the proposed settlement be withdrawn and revised, and
that further proceedings be held.
The Complaint and the Proposed Settlement
The Complaint alleges that Morgan Stanley violated Section 1 of the
Sherman Act \7\ by entering into separate financial derivative
contracts with two major competing sellers in the NYISO electric
capacity market, effectively combining their economic interests. The
Morgan Stanley derivatives reduced the utilities' risk of bidding
strategically to raise the clearing price in the NYISO market, which is
paid to all sellers. As a consequence, higher prices were paid for
capacity by retail utilities, and the costs were passed through to
consumers.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\7\ The Sherman Act provides that Ielvery contract, combination
in the form of trust or otherwise, or conspiracy, in restraint of
trade or commerce among the several States, or with foreign nations,
is declared to be illegal.'' 15 U.S.C. Sec. 1.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Under Morgan Stanley's derivative contract with the largest seller
in the relevant market, Keyspan Corporation (``Keyspan''), Morgan
Stanley paid Keyspan whenever NYISO auction prices exceeded a fixed
level ($7.57/MW). This rewarded Keyspan when it set the NYISO clearing
price at the maximum. Even if all of its capacity was not sold at its
high price, Keyspan was assured of benefitting from it through the
derivative contract. Under Morgan Stanley's parallel derivative
contract with Astoria, Morgan Stanley guaranteed Astoria a fixed floor
price for all its capacity sales, regardless of the prices established
in the NYISO auctions, and Astoria agreed to pay Morgan Stanley
whenever the NYISO auction price exceeded the floor price in the
derivative contract. Morgan Stanley could take profits reaped by
Astoria due to the artificially high price, and give them to Keyspan.
The derivatives thus worked to insure Keyspan against lost profits if
it lost some sales by bidding high, at the market rate cap. They
assured Astoria that it would receive a known fixed price for all of
its capacity, regardless of the outcome of the NYISO auctions.\8\
Morgan Stanley's net profit from the derivatives was $21.6 million.\9\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\8\ There was little risk of low prices that would require
Keyspan to pay Morgan Stanley and Morgan Stanley to pay Astoria
under the derivatives. Keyspan was able to set the clearing price
because at least some of its capacity would be needed, and so it
could confidently demand the ceiling price for all or most of it,
confident that when some of its expensively priced capacity went
unsold, it would receive payments from Morgan Stanley in accordance
their derivative agreement. Keyspan ``consistently bid its capacity
at its cap even though a significant portion of its capacity went
unsold.'' Complaint, p. 9, ] 32.
\9\ Complaint, p. 9, ] 35.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The NYISO pays the market clearing price to all sellers, including
those who offered capacity at a lower price. As a result, the total
economic damage to electric customers exceeds the ill-gotten gains of
Morgan Stanley and the two utilities. There is no quantification or
estimate of this damage to the public and to customers in the Complaint
or other papers in the record. One major capacity buyer, Consolidated
Edison Company of New York, Inc. (``Con Edison''), estimated the
inflated capacity costs to be approximately $159 Million in 2006.\10\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\10\ Of that amount, approximately $119 million was paid by New
York City area utilities, and $39 million was paid by utilities in
the rest of the state. See Motion to Continent of Consolidated
Edison Company of New York, Inc., etc., Re New York Independent
System Operator, FERC Docket No. ER07-360 (Jan. 27, 2009), P. 2 and
Affidavit of Stuart Nachmias, ]] 13-14, available at https://elibrary.ferc.gov/idmws/common/opennatasp?filelD=11236060. The
amount of capacity overcharges in 2007 and until NYISO capacity
market rules were changed in early 2008 were not estimated.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Simultaneously with the filing of the complaint, and without
further proceedings, DOJ and Morgan Stanley filed a proposed Final
Judgment, which embodies their agreement to settle the case. Key
provisions of the Final Judgment are:
Morgan Stanley admits no wrongdoing and the lawsuit is
terminated,
Morgan Stanley agrees to disgorge to the government only
$4.8 million of its $21.6 million profit from its derivative contracts.
Standard of Review
The Tunney Act establishes the procedure and standard of review
applicable to the proposed settlement of an antitrust case brought by
DOJ:
(1) Before entering any consent judgment proposed by the United
States under this section, the court shall determine that the entry of
such judgment is in the public interest. For the purpose of such
determination, the court shall consider--
(A) the competitive impact of such judgment, including termination
of alleged violations, provisions for enforcement and modification,
duration of relief sought, anticipated effects of alternative remedies
actually considered, whether its terms are ambiguous, and any other
competitive considerations bearing upon the adequacy of such judgment
that the court deems necessary to a determination of whether the
consent judgment is in the public interest, and
(B) the impact of entry of such judgment upon competition in the
relevant market or markets, upon the public generally and individuals
alleging specific injury from the violations set forth in the complaint
including consideration of the public benefit, if any, to be derived
from a determination of the issues at trial.
15 U.S.C. Sec. 16(e)(1). (Emphasis added). The Tunney Act standard
was recently applied in the context of the DOJ settlement with Keyspan,
involving the same derivative contract:
[T]he Tunney Act allows courts to weigh, among other things, the
relationship between the allegations set forth in the government's
complaint and the remedy imposed by the proposed final judgment,
whether the proposed final judgment is overly ambiguous, whether the
enforcement mechanisms it employs are adequate, and whether the
proposed final judgment may affirmatively prejudice third parties. See
United States v. Microsoft Corp., 56 F.3d 1448, 1461-62 (DCCir. 1995)
(per curiam). The court may not, however, ``make a de novo
determination of facts and issues'' in conducting its public interest
inquiry. United States v. Western Elec. Co., 993 F.2d 1572, 1577
(DCCir.), cert. denied, 510 U.S. 984, 114 S.Ct. 487, 126 L.Ed.2d 438
(1993) (internal quotation and citation omitted). Rather, ``jtjhe
balancing of competing social and political interests affected by a
proposed antitrust decree must be left, in the first instance, to the
discretion of the Attorney General.'' Id. (internal quotation and
citation omitted). The court should therefore reject the proposed final
judgment only if ``it has exceptional confidence that adverse antitrust
consequences will result--perhaps akin to the confidence that would
justify a court in overturning the predictive judgments of an
administrative agency.'' Microsoft, 56 F.3d at 1460 (internal
quotations and citation omitted).
In conducting its inquiry, the court is not required to hold a
hearing or conduct a trial. See 119 Cong. Rec. 24,598 (1973); United
States v. Airline Tariff Pub. Co., 836 F.Supp. 9, 11 n. 2 (D.D.C.
1993). The Tunney Act expressly allows the court to make its
[[Page 15132]]
public interest determination on the basis of the competitive impact
statement and response to comments alone. A court may, in its
discretion, invoke additional procedures when it determines such
proceedings may assist in the resolution of issues raised by the
comments. See H.R. Rep. No. 93-1463, at 8-9 (1974), reprinted in
U.S.S.C.A.N. 6535, 6539.
United States v. Keyspan, 763 F.Supp.2d 633, 637-638 (S.D.N.Y.
2011) (``Keyspan''), quoting United States v. Enova Corp., 107
F.Supp.2d 10, 17 (D.D.C. 2000) (emphasis added). It is not necessary
for the relief proposed in a settlement to be a perfect remedy for the
alleged antitrust violation, but there must be a factual basis to
support any DOJ conclusions that the remedies proposed are reasonably
adequate.\11\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\11\ There must be ``a factual foundation for the government's
decision such that its conclusions regarding the proposed settlement
are reasonable.'' United States v. Keyspan Corp., 763 F. Supp. 2d
633, 637-38 (S.D.N.Y. 2011) (quoting United States v. Abitibi-
Consolidated Inc., 584 F. Supp. 2d 162, 165 (D.D.C. 2008).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The Keyspan decision, quoted above, misapprehends the standard of
review. The Tunney Act not only ``allows'' courts to consider the
listed factors in its review. It requires such consideration. The
Tunney Act was amended in the Antitrust Criminal Penalty Enhancement
and Reform Act of 2004 specifically to clarify that reviewing courts
``shall'' (instead of ``may'') take each of the *enumerated factors
into account in their review of a proposed antitrust case settlement.
15 U.S.C. Sec. Sec. 16(e)(1)(A) and (B).
AARP demonstrates below that the proposed settlement fails to pass
muster under the standards for approval of DOJ antitrust settlements.
DOJ should withdraw its consent to the settlement, and conduct further
proceedings to develop the record and proceed to trial, if a
renegotiated agreement which addresses the concerns in these comments
cannot be made.
Argument
1. The Proposed Settlement Is Not in the Public Interest Because It
Provides No Benefit to Customers Harmed.
The Morgan Stanley/Keyspan/Astoria derivatives supported gaming of
the NYISO market, causing very serious financial harm to customers by
artificially inflating the NYISO market prices for electric capacity.
The DOJ Complaint and Competitive Impact Statement (``CIS'') very
prominently state that the ``likely effect'' of the alleged antitrust
violation ``was to increase capacity prices for the retail electricity
suppliers who must purchase capacity, and, in turn, to increase the
prices consumers pay for electricity.'' Complaint, pp. 1-2, CIS 1-2
(emphasis added). The prayer for relief in the DOJ Complaint includes a
request for equitable relief to ``dissipate the anticompetitive effects
of the violation.'' Complaint If 40. The only ``anticompetitive
effects'' identified in the record are the artificial increase in NYISO
prices and the higher prices paid by consumers.
The record at this stage contains no evidence of the magnitude of
the injury to consumers, including many AARP members living in the New
York City area. As previously discussed, there are indications outside
the record that the price of capacity was artificially raised by
approximately $157 million in 2006 by the gambit supported by the
Morgan Stanley derivatives, and the term of the agreements went beyond
2006. The New York State Public Service Commission stated in its
comments on the settlement of the Keyspan case arising from the same
transactions that the harm to consumers ``could have totaled hundreds
of millions of dollars.* * *'' \12\ The CIS does not attempt to address
the magnitude of this harm to customers, which far exceeded the total
profits of the participants in the scheme to raise NYISO prices.\13\ As
a consequence, the record is insufficiently developed for a reviewing
court to test whether the remedy proposed is appropriate.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\12\ NYPSC Comments in United States v. Keyspan, available at
https://www.justice_gov/atr/cases/f259700/259704-5.htm.
\13\ The total harm is greater than the profits because under
NYISO market rules, artificially high prices achieved by
participants in the scheme were paid to all sellers.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Under the proposed settlement there is not one penny for the
injured consumers. Instead, the entire $4.8 million of monetary relief
is to be paid to the United States Treasury. This does nothing to
address the injury to those most directly harmed, the electric
customers whose bills were artificially increased. There is no
explanation in the CIS of why this is so.
The Tunney Act requires DOJ, in its CIS, to provide ``a description
and evaluation of alternatives to such proposal actually considered by
the United States.'' 15 U.S.C. Sec. 16(b)(6). The CIS, however,
contains no description or evaluation of alternative relief that would
provide at least some benefit to the injured customers. Any claim by
DOJ that equitable relief for the benefit of injured consumers was
never ``actually considered'' would not be credible. In the Keyspan
case, involving the same derivative agreement, the settlement also
provided no relief to consumers. The absence of any equitable relief
for consumers drew vigorous protest in that case, in the comments of
the New York State Public Service Commission, the New York State
Consumer Protection Board, the City of New York, Con Edison, and AARP.
Surely DOJ would at least have considered, however briefly, whether to
seek some measure of relief for electric customers who suffered from
the wrong.
AARP expects that DOJ, in its response to these comments, will cite
the recent court approval of the Keyspan settlement, which lacked any
relief to customers. That, however, does not bar inclusion of such
relief in the settlement of this case.
In rejecting requests for equitable relief to consumers the court
in the Keyspan case relied upon a perceived ``filed rate'' barrier and
potential ``transaction costs'' of administering monetary relief to
customers, stating:
Finally, this Court rejects the notion that the Consent Decree
should only be approved if the disgorged proceeds are returned to New
York City consumers. While such relief might be optimal, payment of the
disgorged proceeds to the Treasury is nevertheless ``within the reaches
of the public interest.'' Alex. Brown, 963 F. Supp. at 238 (quotations
omitted). It can be effectuated without incurring transaction costs and
inures to the public benefit. See Sec. & Exchange Commin v. Bear,
Steams & Co. Inc:, 626 F. Supp. 2d 402,419 (S.D.N.Y. 2009) (answering
``the question of how [disgorged money] can be used to do 'the greatest
good for the greatest number of people' by ordering its transfer to the
``Treasury to be used by the Government for its operations'').
Moreover, the Government raises valid concerns regarding potential
violation of the filed-rate doctrine.
``The filed rate doctrine bars suits against regulated utilities
grounded on the allegation that the rates charged by the utility are
unreasonable. Simply stated, the doctrine holds that any `filed rate'--
that is, one approved by the governing regulatory agency is per se
reasonable and unassailable in judicial proceedings brought by
ratepayers.'' Wegoland Ltd. v. NYNEX Corp., 27 F.3d 17, 18-19 (2d Cir.
1994); see also Keogh v. Chi. & Northwestern Ry. Co., 260 U.S. 156, 163
(1922) (holding that the filed rate doctrine bars recovery for
antitrust damages against carriers colluding to set artificially high
shipment rates). In view of that prohibition, return of the disgorged
proceeds to New York City electricity customers could circumvent the
filed-rate doctrine. A court must extend ``deference to the
Government's
[[Page 15133]]
evaluation of the case and the remedies available to it.'' Alex. Brown,
963 F. Supp. at 239.
United States v. Keyspan Corp., 763 F. Supp. 2d 633, 643 (S.D.N.Y.
2011) (S.D.N.Y 2011) (emphasis added).
This case does not involve any utility rate filed by Morgan
Stanley. It involves profits extracted from large numbers of customers
by sellers using Morgan Stanley's services and derivative instruments
as tools. Thus the ``filed rate'' rationale for not providing any
relief to customers, perceived by the court to be a barrier in
Keyspan,\14\ clearly is not applicable here.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\14\ At issue was Keyspan's $48 million profit from its
derivative contract with Morgan Stanley. As the contract was neither
filed nor part of Keyspan's rates, which are set by the NYISO in its
auctions, applicability of the ``filed rate'' doctrine to customer
relief in that case is questionable.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The transaction cost issue perceived to be a barrier to customer
relief in Keyspan is also easily hurdled. Just as utilities paid
artificially inflated NYISO charges for capacity and passed those
charges on to their customers, utilities can pass on equitable monetary
relief intended for the benefit of their customers in the normal course
of business without excessive transaction costs. For example, Con
Edison passes on variations in capacity costs to its customers every
month, in monthly rate adjustments, through its ``Market Adjustment
Clause.'' The Market Adjustment Clause takes into account 36 variable
factors every month, including ``(8) certain NYISO-related charges and
credits * * *.'' \15\ is Equitable monetary relief from the inflated
NYISO charges could be provided as a credit to customers in the normal
course of making rate adjustments. Refunds to utility customers
relating to past overcharges are also a well-established remedy.
Section 113 of the New York Public Service Law provides:
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\15\ Con Edison Electric Service Tariff, General Information,
Part VII, A(1)(a)(8), available at https://www.coned.com/documents/elec/159-164a.pdf.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
2. Whenever any public utility company or municipality, whose rates
are subject to the jurisdiction of the commission, shall receive any
refund of amounts charged and collected from it by any source, the
commission shall have power after a hearing, upon its own motion, upon
complaint or upon the application of such public utility company or
municipality, to determine whether or not such refund should be passed
on, in whole or in part, to the consumers of such public utility
company or municipality and to order such public utility company or
municipality to pass such refunds on to its consumers, in the manner
and to the extent determined just and reasonable by the commission.
The New York State Public Service Commission supported the return
of overcharges as equitable relief to customers in Keyspan. Surely the
Public Service Commission would cooperate, if necessary in the
oversight of monetary relief intended for utility customers when a
provision for such relief is contained in an antitrust case settlement.
In sum, unlike Keyspan, there is no ``filed rate'' barrier in this
case, and AARP has demonstrated that consumer benefits could be
efficiently administered without the speculative transaction costs
feared in Keyspan. The proposed remedy allowing the government to
receive all the profits that Morgan Stanley agrees to cede, without
consideration of the amount of harm suffered by customers and without
any equitable relief to the customers, is not equitable and is not in
the public interest.
2. The CIS Should Be Withdrawn or Amended by DOJ To Support Its
Reasons for Termination of the Action With No Finding of Wrongdoing by
Morgan Stanley.
As required by the Tunney Act, DOJ filed a Competitive Impact
Statement (``CIS'') \16\ in which it sets out the facts of the case,
its reasoning and its conclusions in support of the settlement. The DOJ
Antitrust Division Manual, 4th Ed., states that in a CIS, ``[a]ll
material provisions of the proposed judgment should be discussed.''
Id., at IV-57. Notably missing from the CIS in this case, however, is
any discussion by DOJ of the critical provision which allows
termination of the case with no admission of any wrongdoing by Morgan
Stanley. The proposed final judgment states that Morgan Stanley:
\16\ The CIS is available at https://www.justice.gov/atr/cases/f275800/275857.pdf.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
consented to the entry of this Final Judgment without trial or
adjudication of any issue of fact or law, for settlement purposes only,
and without this Final Judgment constituting any evidence against or an
admission by Morgan for any purpose with respect to any claim or
allegation contained in the Complaint * * *.
Proposed Final Judgment, p. 1. The importance of this provision
letting Morgan Stanley off the hook is underscored by the Complaint, in
which DOJ demands ``What the Court adjudge and decree that the Morgan/
Keyspan Swap constitutes an illegal restraint in the sale of installed
capacity in the New York City market in violation of Section 1 of the
Sherman Act.'' Complaint, ] 39. Also, DOJ makes numerous references in
the CIS to Morgan Stanley's conduct as having constituted a violation
of the Sherman Act:
The United States brought this lawsuit against Defendant Morgan
Stanley * * * to remedy a violation of Section 1 of the Sherman Act, 15
U.S.C. Sec. 1. [CIS 1]
The proposed Final Judgment remedies this violation * * * [CIS 2].
Disgorgement will deter Morgan and others from future violations of
the antitrust laws. [CIS 2]
[D]isgorgement will effectively fulfill the remedial goals of the
Sherman Act to ``prevent and restrain'' antitrust violations as it will
send a message of deterrence to those in the financial services
community considering the use of derivatives for anticompetitive ends.
[CIS 9]
Despite these assertions by DOJ in its CIS that there were
violations of the law, it is the Final Judgment that counts most. The
Final Judgment affirmatively disavows any finding or admission that the
law was violated by Morgan Stanley. There is no explanation or factual
basis in the CIS to support DOJ's abandonment in the Final Judgment of
the primary object of the action. It is incumbent upon DOJ to withdraw
and amend its CIS to include its rationale for ending the case with no
finding or admission that Morgan Stanley violated the antitrust laws,
and with no commitment by Morgan Stanley that it will not engage in
similar conduct in the future. The public should then be allowed an
additional opportunity to respond to any amended or new CIS.
With no finding that Section 1 of the Sherman Act is violated by
the use of financial derivatives to backstop risks when sellers game
electricity markets, no one, including Morgan Stanley, really knows
whether this gambit is actually illegal. As a result, Morgan Stanley
and any other future wrongdoers will still lack scienter, an essential
element for criminal sanctions under Section 2 of the Sherman Act.
Thus, future wrongdoers can try the gambit again and need be concerned
only about trivial civil sanctions.
3. DOJ Should Withdraw its Consent to the Settlement or Amend its
CIS to Provide Support for its Conclusion that the Disgorgement
Proposed in this Case will be a Deterrent.
Disgorgement of profits is one of the equitable remedies available
to address violations of the Sherman Act. United States v. Keyspan
Corp., 763 F. Supp. 2d 633, 638-641 (SDNY 2011). DOJ repeatedly
emphasizes the settlement's
[[Page 15134]]
requirement that Morgan Stanley disgorge $4.8 million of its profits
from the derivatives, claiming this payment to the government would
serve as a deterrent:
Disgorgement will deter Morgan and others from future violations of
the antitrust laws. [CIS 2]
The proposed Final Judgment requires Morgan to disgorge profits
gained as a result of its unlawful agreement restraining trade. Morgan
is to surrender $4.8 million to the Treasury of the United States. [CIS
8]
* * * * *
Requiring disgorgement in these circumstances will thus protect the
public interest by deterring Morgan and other parties from entering
into similar financial agreements that result in anticompetitive
effects in the underlying markets, or from otherwise engaging in
similar anticompetitive conduct in the future. [CIS 8]
A disgorgement remedy should deter Morgan and others from engaging
in similar conduct and thus achieves a significant portion of the
relief the United States would have obtained through litigation * * *
[CIS 11]
There is no evidence in the record, however, to support these broad
claims that the settlement crafted by Morgan Stanley and DOJ would have
any deterrent effect on anyone.
According to the CIS, ``Morgan earned approximately $21.6 million
in net revenues from the Morgan/Keyspan Swap and the Morgan/Astoria
Hedge.'' CIS 6 DOJ acknowledges that only a portion of Morgan Stanley's
profits would be disgorged if the proposed settlement is approved,
attempting to put the best light on a small recovery:
While the disgorged sum represents less than all of Morgan's net
transaction revenues under the two agreements, [fn. omitted]
disgorgement will effectively fulfill the remedial goals of the Sherman
Act to ``prevent and restrain'' antitrust violations as it will send a
message of deterrence to those in the financial services community
considering the use of derivatives for anticompetitive ends. [CIS 9]
(emphasis added).
If the 21% to be disgorged under the proposed settlement is ``less
than all'' of the $21.6 million profit, as DOJ puts it, perhaps the
amount of ill-gotten gains retained by Morgan Stanley--$16.8 million,
or 79%--might be said to be ``nearly all'' of the net profit.
The CIS fails to explain how disgorgement of only $4.8 million, and
allowing Morgan Stanley to keep $16.8 million of its profits from the
scheme would deter similar future conduct by Morgan Stanley or anyone.
There is simply no evidence in the record to support DOJ's conclusion
that the proposed settlement ``will send a message of deterrence to
those in the financial services community considering the use of
derivatives for anticompetitive ends.'' Id. Given the minimal
development of the record, no one can see the derivative instruments
used by Morgan Stanley. If the offending derivative agreements are not
disclosed, there is even less likelihood of deterring similar
transactions by others. These should have been provided by DOJ with the
CIS as ``determinative documents.\17\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\17\ The DOJ Competitive Impact Statement asserts there are no
``determinative'' documents required to be submitted under the
Tunney Act. See United States v. Central Contracting Co., Inc., 537
F. Supp. 571 (E.D. Va. 1982).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
DOJ is ordinarily entitled to deference in assessing the
effectiveness of a remedy it agrees to, but here its conclusion that
disgorgement of only $4.8 million is sufficient is refuted by every day
common sense and arithmetic. The CIS does not explain in plain language
how allowing a wrongdoer to keep 79% of its ill-gotten gains can be
seen as any kind of ``message of deterrent.'' Rather, the ``message''
to some may really be that large profits can still be made from gaming
electricity markets using financial derivative agreements to support
bidding strategies. If found out, there will probably be no criminal
antitrust sanction, and at worst one may keep the majority of the
profit in a settlement with DOJ. The real lesson taught by the proposed
settlement to potential manipulators could actually encourage similar
conduct and further harm competition. This is not a remote or
speculative concern. ``Manipulation is a potentially serious problem in
all derivatives markets, energy included.'' \18\ The CIS does not
consider this possibility and therefore does not sufficiently address
the impact on competition as required by the Tunney Act. 15 U.S.C.
Sec. 16(e)(1)(A).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\18\ Craig Pirrong, Energy Market Manipulation: Definition,
Diagnosis, and Deterrence, 31 Energy Law Journal 1-2 (2010)
(emphasis added).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The $4.8 million disgorgement is probably well within the range of
what Morgan Stanley's litigation expenses might be if the case is
litigated. The real lesson of the disclaimer and the small disgorgement
is that this is merely a nuisance settlement. As recently stated by
Judge Rakoff in the course of rejecting a settlement proposed of the
SEC:
[A] consent judgment that does not involve any admissions and that
results in only very modest penalties is just as frequently viewed,
particularly in the business community, as a cost of doing business
imposed by having to maintain a working relationship with a regulatory
agency, rather than as any indication of where the real truth lies.
SEC v Citigroup Global Markets, Inc., 11 Civ. 7387 (Nov. 28, 2011).
4. The CIS Fails to Support the Claim that the Settlement is
Reasonable Because it Avoids Litigation Risk.
DOJ attempts to justify the proposed settlement by invoking its
risk of litigation, i.e., that it might lose the case if it goes to
trial:
The $4.8 million disgorgement amount is the product of settlement
and accounts for litigation risks and costs. [CIS 9]
Had the case against Morgan proceeded to trial, the United States
would have sought disgorgement of the $21.6 million in net transaction
revenues Morgan earned under both the Morgan/Keyspan Swap and the
Morgan/Astoria Hedge. At trial, Morgan--in addition to raising
arguments as to its lack of liability in general--would have disputed
that the entire $21.6 million earned under both agreements would be
cognizable as ill-gotten gains. [CIS 9, fn 4].
While DOJ is ordinarily given considerable deference to its
assessment of the merits of its case, it does not cite any authority or
facts to show that this case is difficult. Based on the CIS and the
record, there are written derivative contracts evidencing the profit-
sharing arrangement of the utility counterparties, facilitated by
Morgan Stanley as middleman. The utilities' bidding records should be
readily available from the NYISO. What is the problem with the case?
DOJ gives no hint that its case is in any way doubtful.
This case is only a variation on classic bid-rigging and price
fixing. Here, Keyspan bid high, in order to elevate the auction price
paid to all sellers, Astoria paid Morgan Stanley some of the extra
profits it made due to the elevated price, and Morgan Stanley paid
Keyspan, keeping a net $21.6 million profit for its services in
facilitating the price raising game. Had the utility sellers made an
agreement bilaterally with the same results, it would be seen as a
crystal clear antitrust violation. See Addyston Pipe & Steel Co. v.
United States, 175 US 211, 243 (1899) (``the defendants enter, not in
truth as competitors, but under an agreement or combination among
themselves which eliminates all competition between them for the
contract, and permits one of their number to make his own bid and
requires the others to bid over him''). It should be equally clear that
a middleman like Morgan Stanley, who
[[Page 15135]]
effectuates the economic alignment of the sellers with its derivative
agreements, is part of the ``combination'' and is also a Sherman Act
violator.
The CIS makes an exaggerated claim that DOJ has won victory in the
proposed settlement, stating:
A disgorgement remedy should deter Morgan and others from engaging
in similar conduct and thus achieves a significant portion of the
relief the United States would have obtained through litigation. * * *
[CIS 11] (emphasis added).
If the $4.8 million to be disgorged is ``a significant portion'' of
the relief sought in the complaint, then the $16.8 million retained by
Morgan Stanley could be said to be three times as ``significant''
because Morgan Stanley keeps the bulk of its profit from facilitating
the scheme.
5. The Keyspan Case Is Not A Barrier to a Consumer Remedy in This
Case.
DOJ relies heavily on the prior decision approving the settlement
of its antitrust case against Keyspan, involving the same derivative
contract, where $12 million of Keyspan's $48 million profit was
disgorged, with no equitable relief for consumers:
Keyspan, pursuant to a Final Judgment sought by the United States,
has surrendered $12 million as a result of its role in the Morgan/
Keyspan Swap.3 See United States v. Keyspan Corp., 763 T. Supp. 2d
633,637-38 (S.D.N.Y. 2011). Securing similar disgorgement from the
other responsible party to the anticompetitive agreement will protect
the public interest by depriving Morgan of a substantial portion of the
fruits of the agreement. The effect of the swap agreement was to
effectively combine the economic interests of Keyspan and Astoria,
thereby permitting Keyspan to increase prices above competitive rates,
and this result could not have been achieved without Morgan's
participation in the swap agreement. Requiring disgorgement in these
circumstances will thus protect the public interest by deterring Morgan
and other parties from entering into similar financial agreements that
result in anticompetitive effects in the underlying markets, or from
otherwise engaging in similar anticompetitive conduct in the future.
CIS 8, (emphasis added). If disgorgement of $4.8 million
constitutes a ``substantial portion of the fruits of the agreement,''
then the amount of ill-gotten profits retained by Morgan Stanley is
three times as ``substantial.''
As the emphasized language in the quotation above shows, the
successful gaming of the NYISO market could not have been achieved by
the utilities without Morgan Stanley acting as middleman. It was not
something Keyspan and Astoria could have accomplished themselves in a
bilateral agreement without flagrant and knowing violation of antitrust
law, which might expose them to possible criminal charges and large
fines under Section 2 of the Sherman Act. Because its role as middleman
was crucial to the scheme, it is appropriate to require Morgan Stanley
to disgorge proportionately more than Keyspan, not less.
The proposed settlement not only fails to ``deprive the antitrust
defendants of the benefits of their conspiracy.'' Intl Boxing Club v.
United States, 358 U.S. 242 at 253 (1959). (quotation omitted), it does
not even come close to that goal. Instead, it allows Morgan Stanley to
retain the lion's share, 79%, of the benefits. ``[A]dequate relief in a
monopolization case should * * * deprive the defendants of any of the
benefits of the illegal conduct * * *'' United States v. Grinnell
Corp., 384 U.S. 563, 577 (1966). Accord, United States v. E.I. du Pont
de Nemours & Co., 366 U.S. 316, 368 (1961) (``Those who violate the Act
may not reap the benefits of their violations * * *'' (quotations
omitted)). In any settlement parties may obtain something less in the
compromise than they initially sought when commencing the litigation,
but the woefully trivial disgorgement by Morgan Stanley of only $4.8
million of its profits cannot possibly be an adequate equitable remedy
or in the public interest.
AARP Recommendations
AARP recommends that DOJ withdraw from the proposed settlement and
proceed in the litigation, or renegotiate with Morgan Stanley to
include the following in any new or revised settlement agreement:
A. Allocation of profits made by Morgan Stanley to provide
equitable relief to electric utility consumers harmed by the violation,
B. Admission by Morgan Stanley of its violation of the Sherman Act
as described in the Complaint,
C. Quantification of the total harm to consumers and markets, and
D. Disgorgement by Morgan Stanley of all profits it realized from
the derivatives used to implement the price raising scheme.
STATE OF NEW YORK DEPARTMENT OF PUBLIC SERVICE
THREE EMPIRE STATE PLAZA, ALBANY, NY 12223-1350
www.dps.state.ny.us
PUBLIC SERVICE COMMISSION
GARRY A. BROWN
Chairman
PATRICIA L ACAMPORA
MAUREEN F. HARRIS
ROBERT E. CURRY JR.
JAMES L LAROCCA
Commissioners
PETER McGOWAN
General Counsel
JACLYN A. BRILLING
Secretary
December 30, 2011
VIA E-MAIL
William H. Stallings, Chief, Transportation Energy & Agriculture
Section, Antitrust Division, United States Department of Justice,
Washington, DC 20530, E-Mail: william.stallings@usdoj.gov.
Re: United States of America v. Morgan Stanley, Civil Case No. 11-civ-
6875 Comments of the Public Service Commission of the State of New York
Dear Chief Stallings:
Pursuant to the Tunney Act, 15 U.S.C. Sec. 16(e)(1), enclosed
please find comments of the Public Service Commission of the State of
New York in response to the notice published in the Federal Register on
October 11, 2011. See U.S. Dep't of Justice, Antitrust Div., United
States v. Morgan Stanley, Proposed Final Judgment and Competitive
Impact Statement, 76 Federal Register 62843 (October 11, 2011).
Please contact me at (518) 474-7663, if you have any questions.
Thank you.
Very truly yours,
Sean Mullany
Assistant Counsel
Enclosure
IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE SOUTHERN DISTRICT OF NEW
YORK
Civil Case No. 11-civ-6875, United States of America, Plaintiff v.
Morgan Stanley, Defendant.
COMMENTS OF THE PUBLIC SERVICE COMMISSION OF THE STATE OF NEW YORK,
PURSUANT TO THE ANTITRUST PROCEDURES AND PENALTIES ACT, ON THE PROPOSED
FINAL JUDGMENT
SUMMARY
The Public Service Commission of the State of New York (``PSC'')
submits
[[Page 15136]]
these comments pursuant to the Antitrust Procedures and Penalties Act,
15 U.S.C. Sec. Sec. 16(b)-(h), in response to the notice published in
the Federal Register on October 11, 2011, in this matter. U.S. Dep't of
Justice, Antitrust Div., United States v. Morgan Stanley, Proposed
Final Judgment and Competitive Impact Statement, 76 Federal Register
62843 (October 11, 2011).
The Department of Justice (``DOJ'') is to be commended for its
faithful enforcement of the antitrust law to protect the integrity of
electricity markets in New York City. The electric capacity market for
New York City is highly concentrated. The antitrust law is properly
applied in this case to address wrongful anti-competitive practices of
Morgan Stanley. DOJ's enforcement of the antitrust law is critical to
protect consumers against the harmful effects of Morgan Stanley's anti-
competitive conduct in this case and, more generally, to protect the
public interest in the integrity of the newly-created competitive
electricity markets.
DOJ proposes to settle this litigation by having Morgan Stanley pay
the United States government $4.8 million. DOJ asserts such a
settlement will be in the public interest because Morgan Stanley's
payment of this amount into the U.S. Treasury will deprive Morgan
Stanley of ``a substantial portion'' of its unjust enrichment.
Competitive Impact Statement, at 8. DOJ admits it seeks only partial
disgorgement of Morgan Stanley's ill-gotten gains, saying that, if it
proceeded to trial, it would have sought disgorgement of all of Morgan
Stanley's net transaction revenues, which DOJ asserts were $21.6
million. Competitive Impact Statement, at 9 & n. 4. DOJ nonetheless
claims the lesser amount of $4.8 million ``will effectively fulfill the
remedial goals of the Sherman Act'' to ``prevent and restrain''
antitrust violations because the settlement will ``send a message of
deterrence'' to the financial services community. Competitive Impact
Statement, at 9. According to DOJ, the lesser amount of $4.8 million
will still prevent market participants from using such financial
agreements to manipulate the capacity markets in the future.
Competitive Impact Statement, at 8-9.
These claims are central to DOJ's assertion that the settlement is
in the public interest, a finding that the Court must make in order to
approve DOJ's proposal. DOJ, however, has offered nothing to support
its claims that this settlement, which would allow Morgan Stanley to
retain almost 80 percent of its ill-gotten gains, will deter such
anticompetitive conduct. Because of this, DOJ has not demonstrated that
this settlement will achieve a central purpose of the Sherman Antitrust
Act, namely preventing anticompetitive arrangements such as those
facilitated by Morgan Stanley in this case. POINT I, below.
To remedy this, the Court should, under the authority of the Tunney
Act, direct DOJ to supplement the record to show how and why the
settlement will prevent such violations from recurring. POINT II,
below.
DOJ has not shown that a settlement for $4.8 million would be
reasonable. DOT alleges Morgan Stanley's net revenues were $21.6
million. It asserts that $4.8 million is reasonable given the risks and
costs of fully litigating the case. However, DOJ has offered only a
summary statement of Morgan Stanley's anticipated position at trial.
Competitive Impact Statement, at 9 & n. 4. This statement does not shed
light on the actual risks and costs of litigation. Moreover, in
considering whether a $4.8 million settlement would be reasonable, the
Court should weigh the nature of Morgan Stanley's wrongdoing, the
impact of such a settlement on DOJ's enforcement role, and the overall
efficacy of antitrust law as a mechanism for preventing such harmful
market manipulation.
DOJ has already settled with KeySpan for $12 million, an amount
equal to 24.5 percent of KeySpan's alleged wrongful gain. That
settlement was approved by the court on February 2, 2011. United States
v. KeySpan Corporation, 10 Civ. 1415 (WHP) Memorandum and Order,
(S.D.N.Y. Feb. 2, 2011). Now DOJ proposes to settle with Morgan
Stanley, the financial institution that allegedly actively facilitated
KeySpan's wrongful manipulation of the capacity market. DOJ alleges
that KeySpan, knowing it could not directly buy an interest in Astoria
(its largest competitor), enlisted Morgan Stanley to act as an
intermediary. Thus, Morgan Stanley's involvement was designed to allow
KeySpan to do indirectly what it could not do directly. In effect, DOJ
alleges that Morgan Stanley actively facilitated KeySpan's attempt to
evade the law. Despite allegations of such egregious conduct, DOJ
proposes to settle with Morgan Stanley for only 22.2 percent of Morgan
Stanley's wrongful gain. Such an arrangement, however, is more akin to
a tax than a penalty.
The settlement amount is particularly unreasonable given the fact
that Morgan Stanley's illegal conduct had a much larger harmful impact.
As the PSC noted in its comments on DOJ's earlier settlement with
KeySpan, the illegal market manipulation that KeySpan and Morgan
Stanley orchestrated imposed unnecessary costs on consumers which may
have totaled tens of millions of dollars. Even if DOJ could not recover
all those damages under the Sherman Antitrust Act, the reasonableness
of seeking only 22.2 percent of what DOJ can recover should be
measured, in part at least, by the larger consumer harm KeySpan and
Morgan Stanley caused. United States v. KeySpan Corporation, 10 Civ.
1415 (S.D.N.Y.) (WHP), Comments of the Public Service Commission of the
State of New York, Pursuant To the Antitrust Procedures and Penalties
Act, On the Proposed Finaljudgment, (Apr. 30, 2010). POINT III, below.
BACKGROUND
In this civil antitrust action, brought DOJ under Section 1 of the
Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. Sec. 1, the government seeks equitable and
other relief against Morgan Stanley for violating the antitrust law.
According to DOJ, in late 2005 and early 2006, Morgan Stanley entered
into a ``swap'' agreement with KeySpan Corporation (``KeySpan''), then
the largest electricity producer in the New York City metropolitan
area. DOJ asserts this agreement (the ``Morgan/KeySpan Swap'') ensured
that KeySpan would withhold substantial output from the New York City
electric generating capacity market, thereby discouraging competitive
bidding and increasing capacity prices. On or about the same time,
Morgan Stanley entered into an offsetting ``swap'' agreement with
Astoria--KeySpan's largest competitor (the ``Morgan/Astoria Swap'').
Morgan Stanley, acting as the intermediary between KeySpan and Astoria,
extracted revenues for its role. Thus, Morgan Stanley facilitated an
arrangement ``[t]he likely effect * * * was to increase capacity prices
for the retail electricity suppliers who must purchase capacity, and,
in turn, to increase the prices consumers pay for electricity.'' 76
Federal Register, at 62844.
According to DOJ, the Morgan/KeySpan Swap unlawfully restrained
competition in New York City's electric capacity market. KeySpan
entered into that agreement to protect itself against increased losses
from its preferred bidding strategy, due to the entry of new
competitors into the capacity market. 76 Federal Register, at 62844.
Under the Morgan/KeySpan Swap, KeySpan, which already possessed
substantial market power in the highly concentrated and constrained New
York City capacity market, ``enter[ed] into an agreement that gave it a
financial interest in the capacity of Astoria-- KeySpan's largest
competitor.'' 76
[[Page 15137]]
Federal Register, at 62844. By giving KeySpan revenues not only from
its own sales, but also from the capacity sales of its largest
competitor, the Morgan/KeySpan Swap ``effectively eliminated KeySpan's
incentive to compete for sales'' of capacity. 76 Federal Register, at
62846. Thus, ``[t]he clear tendency of the Morgan/KeySpan Swap was to
alter KeySpan's bidding in the NYC Capacity Market auctions.'' 76
Federal Register, at 62846.
As a result, electric capacity prices remained unlawfully inflated,
and Morgan Stanley earned approximately $21.6 million in net revenues
from the Morgan/KeySpan Swap and the Morgan/Astoria Swap. 76 Federal
Register, at 62846. In addition, the elimination of competitive
pressures, due to the anti-competitive Morgan/KeySpan Swap imposed
unnecessary costs on consumers which may have totaled tens of millions
of dollars.
POINT I
DOJ HAS NOT PROVIDED ENOUGH INFORMATION TO DETERMINE WHETHER THE
PROPOSED SETTLEMENT IS IN THE PUBLIC INTEREST
Before entering any consent judgment proposed by the United States,
the court must first determine that entry of such a judgment ``is in
the public interest.'' 15 U.S.C. Sec. 16(e)(1). In doing so, ``the
court shall consider--
(A) the competitive impact of such judgment, including termination
of alleged violations, provisions for enforcement and modification,
duration of relief sought, anticipated effects of alternative remedies
actually considered, whether its terms are ambiguous, and any other
competitive considerations bearing upon the adequacy of such judgment
that the court deems necessary to a determination of whether the
consent judgment is in the public interest; and
(B) the impact of entry of such judgment upon competition in the
relevant market or markets, upon the public generally and individuals
alleging specific injury from the violations set forth in the complaint
including consideration of the public benefit, if any, to be derived
from a determination of the issues at trial.
15 U.S.C. Sec. 16(e)(1)(A) &(B).
In seeking this Court's approval, DOJ has the burden to ``provide a
factual basis for concluding that the settlements are reasonably
adequate remedies for the alleged harms.'' United States v. SBC
Communs., Inc., 489 F. Supp. 2d 1, 17 (D.D.C. 2007). In this case, DOJ
has not met this burden. Neither the competitive impact statement, nor
the proposed consent decree provides the information needed to evaluate
whether this settlement would be a reasonably adequate remedy for the
harm caused by KeySpan.
Under the proposed settlement, Morgan Stanley would be required to
pay the United States government a total of $4.8 million dollars.
United States v. Morgan Stanley, Proposed Final Judgment and
Competitive Impact Statement, 76 Federal Register 62843, 9949 (October
11, 2011). According to DOJ, this amount ``remedies [Morgan Stanley's]
violation by requiring Morgan to disgorge profits obtained through the
anticompetitive agreement.'' 76 Federal Register, at 62846. According
to DOJ, ``[d]isgorgement will deter Morgan and others from future
violations of the antitrust laws.'' 76 Federal Register, at 62846.
Thus, according to DOJ, the public interest is served because the
proposed settlement will both prevent Morgan Stanley's unjust
enrichment, and will deter such wrongful conduct in the future.
Preventing Morgan Stanley's unjust enrichment is a legitimate
purpose of any proposed settlement. In fashioning relief in response to
a violation of the antitrust law, ``[o]ne of [the] objectives * * * is
to 'deny to the defendant the fruits of its statutory violation.''
Massachusetts v. Microsoft Corp., 373 F.3d 1199, 1232 (DC Cir. 2004)
(quoting United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34, 103 (DC Cir.
2001)). However, the unstated premise underlying DOJ's claims (that
disgorgement is necessary to prevent unjust enrichment, and a $4.8
million penalty is adequate) is that Morgan Stanley's unjust enrichment
totaled only $4.8 million. Yet DOJ itself asserts that Morgan Stanley's
net revenues totaled $21.6 million. 76 Federal Register, at 62847.
Thus, DOJ itself acknowledges it is seeking only partial disgorgement.
DOJ nonetheless claims such partial disgorgement will ``send a
message of deterrence[,]'' thereby ``deterring Morgan and other parties
from entering into similar financial agreements ... or from otherwise
engaging in similar anticompetitive conduct in the future.'' 76 Federal
Register, at 62848. While these claims are central to DOJ's contention
that the settlement would be in the public interest, DOJ has not
offered any evidence to support the proposition that this settlement
will act as a deterrent. This lack of evidence showing the settlement
would prevent and deter such conduct is a critical omission. As DOJ
acknowledges, preventing and restraining antitrust violations are ``the
remedial goals'' of the Sherman Antitrust Act. 76 Federal Register; at
62848. Yet the absence of any evidence supporting these claims makes it
virtually impossible for the Court to meaningfully evaluate whether a
$4.8 million settlement ``represents a reasonable method of eliminating
the consequences of the illegal conduct.'' National Soc. of
Professional Engineers v. United States, 435 U.S. 679, 698 (1978). This
holds true both with respect to depriving Morgan Stanley of its unjust
enrichment, and with respect to evaluating whether the settlement will
deter such wrongful conduct in the future. Thus, on the current record,
the Court has no basis for finding the proposed settlement would be
``in the public interest.''
Given what DOJ has presented, the settlement would not be in the
public interest. DOJ seeks only partial disgorgement, so the settlement
would not prevent Morgan Stanley's unjust enrichment, since anything
less than full disgorgement would not fully strip Morgan Stanley of its
wrongful gains. The proposed settlement amount, however, is only a
minor fraction (22.2%) of Morgan Stanley's unjust enrichment.\1\ Why
would such a penalty deter similar violations of the antitrust law in
the future? Common sense suggests that such an amount will instead be
viewed as merely a cost of doing business. S.E.C. v. Citigroup Global
Markets, Inc., Slip Op. at 10 (S.D.N.Y. Nov. 28, 2011) (``[A] consent
judgment that does not involve any admissions and that results in only
very modest penalties is just as frequently viewed, particularly in the
business community, as a cost of doing business imposed by having to
maintain a working relationship with a regulatory agency * * *'').
Allowing Morgan Stanley to retain almost 80 percent of its ill-gotten
gains can hardly be characterized as an effective deterrent without
something more to support
[[Page 15138]]
such a claim.\2\ Thus, the proposed $4.8 million settlement would not
satisfy either of DOJ's rationales (i.e., preventing Morgan Stanley's
unjust enrichment, and deterring such wrongful conduct in the future)
for a judicial finding that the settlement is in the public interest.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1\ In approving DOJ's earlier $12 million settlement with
KeySpan, the court noted that, according to DOJ, KeySpan ``did not
necessarily earn additional revenues'' by not competing. Instead,
the swap offered greater revenue certainty even though ``competing
could have earned the company greater revenues * * *'' United States
v. KeySpan Corporation, 10 Civ. 1415 (WHP) Memorandum and Order, at
14-15 (S.D.N.Y. Feb. 2, 2011). Because of this, in part, the Court
found the $12 million settlement with KeySpan to be reasonable.
Here, Morgan Stanley's swap revenues (aside from transactional
costs) were profits since it would have had no revenues if KeySpan
competed instead of entering into the swap. Accordingly, the court's
rationale for finding the KeySpan settlement amount reasonable does
not support this proposed settlement with Morgan Stanley.
\2\ Arguably, even total disgorgement would have only a limited
deterrent effect. ``[T]o 'limit the penalty * * * to disgorgement is
to tell a violator that he may [break the law] with virtual
impunity; if he gets away undetected, he can keep the proceeds, but
if caught, he simply has to be give back the profits of his wrong.''
SEC v. Bear, Stearns & Co., 626 F. Supp. 2d 402,406 (S.D.N.Y. 2009)
(quoting SE.C. v. Rabinovich & Assoc., 2008 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 93595,
2008 WL 4937360, at *6 (S.D.N.Y. Nov. 18, 2008)).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
POINT II
THE COURT SHOULD DIRECT DOJ TO SUPPLEMENT THE RECORD ON THE DETERRENT
EFFECT(S) OF THE PROPOSED SETTLEMENT
The Morgan/KeySpan Swap, in both purpose and effect, violated the
antitrust law. Its purpose was to ``effectively eliminate[] KeySpan's
incentive to compete for sales in the same way a purchase of Astoria or
a direct agreement between KeySpan and Astoria would have done.'' 76
Federal Register, at 62848. Thus, regardless of its effect on the
market, the Morgan/KeySpan Swap violated the Sherman Act. Cf. Summit
Health v. Pinhas, 500 U.S. 322, 330 (1991) (1131ecause the essence of
any violation of Sec. 1 [of the Sherman Act] is the illegal agreement
itself[,] rather than the overt acts performed in furtherance of it, *
* * proper analysis focuses, not upon actual consequences, but rather
upon the potential harm that would ensue if the conspiracy were
successful'').
The Morgan/KeySpan Swap also violated the Sherman Act because of
its effect on the market. Its ``clear tendency'' was to alter KeySpan's
bidding, in order to prevent competition and keep prices high. 76
Federal Register, at 62848. CI United States v. Stasztcuk, 517 F.2d 53,
60 & n.17 (7th Cir. Ill. 1975) (``The federal power to protect the free
market may be exercised to punish conduct which threatens to impair
competition even when no actual harm results'').
However, because, as discussed in POINT I, DOJ has not proffered
evidence sufficient to enable the Court to evaluate whether the
proposed settlement is in the public interest, DOJ should be directed
to do so. Under-the Tunney Act, ``[t]he court may `take testimony of
Government officials or experts' as it deems appropriate, 15 U.S.C.
16(f)(1); authorize participation by interested persons, including
appearances by amici curiae, id. Sec. 16(f)(3); review comments and
objections filed with the Government concerning the proposed judgment,
as well as the Government's response thereto, id. Sec. 16(f)(4); and
`take such other action in the public interest as the court may deem
appropriate,' id. Sec. 16(f)(5).'' Massachusetts v. Microsoft Corp.,
373 F.3d 1199, 1206 (DC Cir. 2004).
Requiring DOJ to adduce facts relating to whether such a minimal
penalty will prevent and deter such anti-competitive conduct will
provide a record basis for any public interest determination made by
the Court. Cf. SE.0 v. Bank Of America Corp., -------- F. Supp.2d------
--, 2010 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 15460 (S.D.N.Y. Feb. 22, 2010) (approving a
proposed consent judgment because, inter alia, after the court rejected
an earlier proposed settlement, the parties conducted extensive
discovery which established facts supporting the new proposal).
POINT III
THE REASONABLENESS OF THE PROPOSED SETTLEMENT SHOULD BE EVALUATED IN
LIGHT OF THE RATEPAYER HARM CAUSED BY MORGAN STANLEY
In determining whether the settlement is in ``the public
interest,'' the Court should consider the impact of the proposed
settlement on the ratepayers that were harmed by Morgan Stanley's anti-
competitive conduct. See 15 U.S.C. Sec. 16(e)(1)(B) (``the court shall
consider the impact of entry of such judgment upon * * * the public
generally * * *'').\3\ DOJ acknowledges ratepayers were harmed, in the
form of inflated capacity prices, because of Morgan Stanley's conduct.
According to DOJ, ``[w]ithout the Morgan/KeySpan Swap, KeySpan likely
would have chosen from a range of potentially profitable competitive
strategies in response to the entry of new capacity. Had it done so,
the price of capacity would have declined.'' 76 Federal Register; at
62846. Because KeySpan decided to withhold capacity rather than
compete, ratepayers were harmed in amounts far exceeding Morgan
Stanley's $21.6 million in wrongful profit.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\3\ Cf. United States v. SBC Communs., Inc., 489 F. Supp. 2d 1,
17 (D.D.C. 2007) (``the court should be concerned with any
allegations that the proposed settlement will injure a third
party'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Yet, in its earlier settlement with KeySpan, DOJ indicated
ratepayers may have no recourse under the antitrust law because of the
``filed rate'' doctrine. See 75 Federal Register, at 9951. Moreover,
ratepayers may not be able to obtain any relief from FERC because, in
early 2008, well before DOJ brought its civil antitrust action against
KeySpan, FERC's Staff concluded there was no evidence that KeySpan's
bidding behavior violated FERC's Anti-Manipulation Rule, 18 C.F.R.
Sec. 1c2(a). FERC Docket Nos. IN08-2-000 & EL07-39-000, Enforcement
Staff Report, Findings of a Non-Public Investigation of Potential
Market Manipulation by Suppliers in the New York City Capacity Market,
p. 17 (February 28, 2008). Thus, in this case ratepayers harmed by
KeySpan's anti-competitive conduct may have no meaningful recourse
under either the antitrust law or the Federal Power Act.
Even if DOJ could not recover damages under the Sherman Antitrust
Act for harm suffered by ratepayers, and is limited to Morgan Stanley's
$21.6 million total net revenues, the Court should, when weighing the
reasonableness of settling for roughly 20 cents on the dollar, consider
the larger consumer harm Morgan Stanley caused, and the apparent lack
of any other effective remedy for consumers that were harmed. This lack
of a remedy for customers is highly significant given the potential
size of the consumer harm Morgan Stanley caused by violating the
antitrust law. Yet DOJ has not offered any evidence of how much Morgan
Stanley's alleged illegal conduct increased electricity capacity market
prices.
If Morgan Stanley's illegal conduct harmed consumers by preventing
price declines that could have totaled tens of millions of dollars,
then the proposed $4.8 million settlement is so low it would not be
fair, reasonable, adequate or in the public interest. Cf. S.E.C. v.
Bank Of America Corp., 653 F. Supp.2d 507 (S.D.N.Y. 2009) (disapproving
a proposed settlement in part because the proposed $33 million fine was
``a trivial penalty for a false statement that materially infected a
multi-billion-dollar merger''). But 4: S.E.C. v. Bank Of America Corp.,
-------- F. Supp.2d--------, 2010 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 15460 (S.D.N.Y. Feb.
22, 2010) (approving a $150 million fine even though it would have only
``a very modest impact on corporate practices or victim
compensation'').
Accordingly, the Court should direct DOJ to address this defect in
the settlement proposal. Although exactitude is not required, some
evidence should be proffered on this point. See New York v. Julius
Nasso Concrete corp., 202 F.3d 82, 88-89 (2d Cir. 2000) (``Where * * *
there is a dearth of market information unaffected by the collusive
action of the
[[Page 15139]]
defendants, the plaintiff's burden of proving damages, is, to an
extent, lightened[,] [and] the State need only provide the court with
some relevant data from which the district court can make a reasonable
estimated calculation of the harm suffered.* * *'') (citations and
internal quotations omitted); id, 202 F.3d at 89 rino do otherwise
would be a perversion of fundamental principles of justice [and would]
deny all relief to the injured person, and thereby relieve the
wrongdoer from making any amends for his acts''); New York v.
Hendrickson Bros., Inc., 840 F.2d 1065, 1078 (2d Cir. 1988) (``The most
elementary conceptions of justice and public policy require that the
wrongdoer shall bear the risk of the uncertainty which his own wrong
has created') (quoting Bigelow v. RKO Radio Pictures, Inc., 327 U.S.
251, 264 (1946)); Fishman v. Estate of Wirtz, 807 F.2d 520, 551 (7th
Cir. Ill. 1986) (``The concept of a `yardstick' measure of damages,
that is, linking the plaintiffs experience in a hypothetical free
market to the experience of a comparable firm in an actual free market,
is also well accepted'').
CONCLUSION
For the reasons stated above, the Court should direct DOJ to
supplement the record to demonstrate why this settlement will prevent
such violations in the future.
Respectfully submitted,
Peter McGowan
General Counsel
By: Sean Mullany, Assistant Counsel Of Counsel, Public Service
Commission, Of the State of New York, Three Empire State Plaza, Albany,
New York 12223-1350.
Dated: December 30, 2011, Albany, New York
[FR Doc. 2012-5952 Filed 3-13-12; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE M