Request for Information on the State of the Offshore Renewable Energy Industry-Auction Format Information Request (AFIR), 76174-76177 [2011-31222]
Download as PDF
76174
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 234 / Tuesday, December 6, 2011 / Notices
Number of
respondents
Reporting Burden .....................................................................................
Total Estimated Burden Hours: 1,010.
Status: New collection.
Authority: Section 3507 of the Paperwork
Reduction Act of 1995, 44 U.S.C. 35, as
amended.
Dated: November 23, 2011.
Colette Pollard,
Departmental Reports Management Officer,
Office of the Chief Information Officer.
BILLING CODE 4210–67–P
DEPARTMENT OF THE INTERIOR
Bureau of Ocean Energy Management
[Docket BOEM–2011–0095]
Request for Information on the State of
the Offshore Renewable Energy
Industry—Auction Format Information
Request (AFIR)
Bureau of Ocean Energy
Management (BOEM), Interior.
ACTION: Request for information.
AGENCY:
BOEM invites public
comment on a proposed set of auction
formats which may be used to issue
commercial renewable energy leases on
the Outer Continental Shelf (OCS).
BOEM is examining several auction
formats, each designed to efficiently
issue renewable energy leases to those
who value them most and are best
positioned to develop them, while also
ensuring that the government receives a
fair return in exchange. BOEM is
focusing primarily on variations of
Ascending Clock Auctions and Package
Auctions formats described in more
detail below. BOEM is also considering
a multiple factor auction approach in
which bidders can earn a discount on
their bids submitted under one of the
auction formats noted above, based on
company-specific attributes deemed
relevant to the success of their projects.
The auction format selected for each
sale area would likely vary based on the
actual characteristics of that sale. Such
characteristics could include the size
and homogeneity of the area to be
offered. BOEM will hold a workshop to
help familiarize stakeholders with the
auction format options and to solicit
feedback on Friday, December 16, 2011,
at the South Interior Building in
Washington, DC.
DATES: Comments should be submitted
electronically or postmarked no later
jlentini on DSK4TPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:04 Dec 05, 2011
Jkt 226001
35
50
than January 20, 2012. All written
comments received during the comment
period will be made available to the
public and considered during
preparation of Proposed Sale Notices
(PSN) pertaining to the competitive
leasing of OCS lands to support the
development of offshore wind energy
resources.
Potential auction
participants, Federal, state, and local
government agencies, tribal
governments, and other interested
parties are requested to submit their
written comments on the contents of
this AFIR in one of the following ways:
1. Electronically: https://www.
regulations.gov. In the entry titled
‘‘Enter Keyword or ID,’’ enter BOEM–
2011–0095 then click ‘‘search.’’ Follow
the instructions to submit public
comments and view supporting and
related materials available for this
document.
2. Written Comments: In written form,
delivered by hand or by mail, enclosed
in an envelope labeled ‘‘Comments on
Offshore Wind AFIR’’ to: Economics
Division, Bureau of Ocean Energy
Management, 381 Elden Street, MS
4050, Herndon, Virginia 20170–4817.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: Greg
Adams, BOEM Economics Division, 381
Elden Street, MS 4050, Herndon,
Virginia 20170–4817, (703) 787–1537 or
greg.adams@boem.gov; or Wright Frank,
BOEM Office of Renewable Energy
Programs, 381 Elden Street, HM 1328,
Herndon, Virginia 20170, (703) 787–
1325 or wright.frank@boem.gov.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION:
ADDRESSES:
[FR Doc. 2011–31259 Filed 12–5–11; 8:45 am]
SUMMARY:
Annual
responses
Authority
This request for information is
published pursuant to subsection 8(p) of
the OCS Lands Act (43 U.S.C. 1337(p)),
as amended by section 388 of the Energy
Policy Act of 2005 (EPAct) and the
implementing regulations at 30 CFR
585.116, which authorize the Director of
BOEM to solicit information from
industry and other relevant stakeholders
to evaluate the state of the offshore
renewable energy industry, including
economic matters that promote or
detract from continued development.
The information received may be used
to evaluate program options to promote
safe and environmentally responsible
development in a manner that ensures
a fair value for use of the nation’s OCS.
PO 00000
Frm 00055
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
Hours per
response
Burden
hours
58
×
1,010
Purpose of the AFIR
The purpose of this information
request is to invite public comment on
the auction format options described in
this request. Due to the complexities
associated with lease valuation and
optimal lease configurations, renewable
energy leasing will require more diverse
approaches than the sealed-bid, cash
bonus approach used to issue offshore
oil and gas leases.
The auction formats and their
specifications are designed to address
important program objectives,
including:
• Fair Return: BOEM is statutorily
required to obtain a ‘‘fair return’’ for
leases and grants on the OCS;
• Economic Efficiency: The lease
auction process should try to ensure
that commercial renewable energy
leases on the OCS are awarded to those
who value the areas the most;
• Program Efficiency: The lease
auction process must be manageable for
BOEM to administer;
• Lease Boundary Flexibility: Within
constraints fixed by BOEM, the auction
should allow bidders to identify the
optimal lease areas;
• Competition: The lease auction
process must be fair, and encourage
participation from all interested bidders;
• Transparency: The lease auction
process must be an open one in which
bids are comparable and the reason why
the winners won is clear;
• Neutrality: The lease auction
process must ensure that all bidders are
treated equally;
• Simplicity: The lease auction
process must be easily understood and
implemented, by both the bidders and
BOEM; and
• Consistency: The lease auction
process should be applicable to the
issuance of leases in a variety of
potential renewable energy
development contexts.
BOEM contracted with Power
Auctions LLC to study auction formats
for issuing renewable energy leases
(hereinafter, ‘‘Ausubel and Cramton
(2011a), (2011b), and (2011c),’’
respectively). Based on its findings and
BOEM’s own internal research, BOEM
has identified several potentially
suitable auction formats. A more
comprehensive discussion of these
auction formats prepared by BOEM
staff, along with the Power Auctions
LLC study, can be found on BOEM’s
E:\FR\FM\06DEN1.SGM
06DEN1
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 234 / Tuesday, December 6, 2011 / Notices
Web site at https://www.boem.gov/
Renewable-Energy-Program/RegulatoryInformation/Renewable-Energy-AuctionFormats.aspx.
jlentini on DSK4TPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
Preference for Bidding on the Cash
Bonus
Although BOEM has the authority to
conduct an auction with either the cash
bonus or operating fee rate as the bid
variable, the bureau generally prefers
using the cash bonus. Conducting an
auction with the bonus bid as the
variable has a number of benefits. It
allows straightforward comparison of
competing offers and tends to award
leases to developers with good financial
backing. Because the winning bidders
would need to pay the bonus bid before
the lease is issued, it prevents
undercapitalized bidders from
committing to a greater payment than
they can afford. Refer to Section 2.3 in
Ausubel and Cramton (2011a) for
further discussion.
Single Lot Auctions: Simple Ascending
Clock Auction Format
In a single lot auction, there is only
one object of bidding (‘‘lot’’), and the
entire lease area would be auctioned off
as a single entity. BOEM could use a
single lot auction in situations where it
is expected that only one lease would be
practical for the available acreage,
because the area would not be large
enough to support multiple projects.
In a single lot auction utilizing an
ascending clock auction format, BOEM
would set an initial asking price for the
single lot, and bidders would indicate
whether or not they are interested in
bidding for that lot at that price. If
BOEM received more than one bid,
BOEM would increase the asking price,
which ‘‘ticks’’ up like a clock, until only
a single bidder is willing to meet the
announced price. This format enables
price discovery by the bidders during
the auction and reduces the guesswork
required for bidders to value offshore
leases.
One complication of the simple
ascending clock auction is that a tiebreaking procedure is needed when all
the remaining bidders drop out in the
same round. Exit bids are one practical
way of solving this problem in the
single lot case. An exit bid allows
bidders who are unwilling to meet the
next round’s bid price to specify the
maximum price they would be willing
to pay short of the new asking price. If
all remaining bidders drop out from one
round to the next, the bidder with the
highest exit bid would prevail. Another
tie-breaking procedure would be for
BOEM to incrementally reduce the
current asking price until one bidder
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:04 Dec 05, 2011
Jkt 226001
bids. In either approach, if the tie
persists after the tie-breaking procedure,
the winner could be determined based
on a random draw. Refer to Section 5.2
in Ausubel and Cramton (2011c) for
further discussion.
Multiple Lot Auctions: Simultaneous
Ascending Clock Auction Format
In most lease sales, BOEM expects to
issue multiple commercial renewable
energy leases in the same auction. In
this case, BOEM is considering the use
of a Simultaneous Ascending Clock
Auction (SACA).
In such a lease sale, BOEM would
divide the entire area offered for leasing
into smaller lots which would be the
objects of the bidding. To form the lots,
BOEM would likely use OCS lease
blocks (approximately 3 statute miles by
3 statute miles), aliquots (squares 1/16th
that size), or some combination of these.
The auction would enable bidding on
all of the lots simultaneously.
BOEM would set a minimum asking
price for each lot. Bidders would bid on
the combination of lots they are
interested in at that price. The bid price
set by BOEM for contested lots (those
receiving two or more bids) would
increase in the next round, while the
price for uncontested lots (those
receiving zero or one bid) would remain
the same in the next round. BOEM
would publish the announced prices
and the number of bids on each lot at
the outset of each round in the auction.
A lot which is uncontested through
several rounds may become contested
because, as the auction proceeds, a
bidder can shift its bids, for example,
from a contested lot to an uncontested
lot. If a bidder submits the only bid on
a particular lot, the standing price for
that lot remains unchanged through
subsequent rounds until an additional
bid is submitted on that lot at the
standing bid price, or the auction ends.
As soon as an uncontested lot receives
more than one bid, it is treated as a
contested lot.
If any bidder finds that it has
submitted a bid on a contested lot, in
the next round that bidder can either:
• Meet the new asking price for this
lot;
• Drop its bid for this lot and submit
a new bid elsewhere; or
• Drop its bid for this lot and not
submit a new bid elsewhere.
The auction ends when no lot has
more than one bid at the last-announced
asking price set by BOEM. Because any
bidder can move a bid from a contested
lot to another lot, the auction for any
particular lot is not over until bidding
has concluded for all lots. The winning
bidders are those with active bids in the
PO 00000
Frm 00056
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
76175
final round and they are obligated to
pay the final round prices for the lots
they win.
Bidding in a SACA auction must
comply with a set of rules that BOEM
will include in the Proposed and Final
Sale Notices. For example:
• A bidder may only bid on
contiguous lots to form a single lease.
• Bidders who want to acquire
multiple lease areas must register for the
auction as separate bidding entities.
• Bidders may maintain or reduce the
number of lots they bid on from one
round to the next; but they may not
increase the number of lots they bid on
from one round to the next. This helps
to control certain opportunities for
gaming, and drives the auction towards
a timely conclusion.
• A ‘‘bid eligibility rule’’ would
determine the maximum number of lots
that a bidder is eligible to bid on in the
auction in the opening round, or in any
subsequent round of the auction.
Bidders’ eligibility is based on the
amount of money posted as their bid
deposit. The maximum number of lots
that a bidder may bid on equals the
maximum number of lots that would be
covered by the bidder’s deposit at the
opening bid price.
• Bidders may submit an exit bid
amount for a particular set of lots in any
round. An exit bid can only win if the
auction ends in that round, and there is
no higher bid on any of the lots in the
set. If any of these conditions is not met,
the bid is set aside and the bidder exits
the auction.
The SACA format provides an
opportunity for price discovery like the
ascending clock auction format used to
bid on a single item. Also, the SACA
format permits a bidder to identify
combinations of lots which support its
particular plan for a commercial
offshore wind energy project. Refer to
Section 5 in Ausubel and Cramton
(2011a) for further discussion of clock
auctions and Section 5.3.5 in Ausubel
and Cramton (2011c) (Alternative I) for
an example of how they work.
One potential problem with the SACA
format arises when multiple bidders
who have submitted bids on the same
lots simultaneously drop out of the
auction. In this situation, designing and
implementing tiebreaking rules becomes
complex. Under the sample rules
described above, because bidders may
not increase the number of lots on
which they bid from one round to the
next, large and potentially high-value
areas in the auction area may go
unclaimed (hereinafter, ‘‘undersell’’).
The difficulty of designing effective exit
bidding rules for multiple lot auctions
limits their potential effectiveness in
E:\FR\FM\06DEN1.SGM
06DEN1
76176
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 234 / Tuesday, December 6, 2011 / Notices
jlentini on DSK4TPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
addressing undersell. As a result, it may
be a challenge to fully achieve program
goals such as optimal configuration of
the winning sets of packages and
ensuring receipt of fair value with the
SACA format.
Alternative for Multiple Lot Auctions:
Package Auctions
Several variations of the package
auction format merit consideration for
leasing packages of lots for offshore
development of electricity from wind
resources. Below are brief outlines of
three such package auction variants.
More detailed descriptions of these
auction formats are available on BOEM’s
web site. A ‘‘package’’ is the
arrangement of lots that a given bidder
has selected in a given round of bidding
paired with the price the bidder is
willing to pay in that round for that
arrangement of lots.
• One variant is a single-phase
package clock auction where the
bidding would proceed just like a
SACA. However, BOEM could select the
best arrangement of packages from
earlier rounds of the auction to
maximize seller revenue, perhaps
subject to the condition that the
prevailing bids in the final round are
included in the winning set of lots. If
the SACA phase of bidding resulted in
a significant undersell, BOEM could
revive early round bids to ‘‘fill in’’
undersold areas.
• A second variant builds on the first
variation, but allows bidders to add a
number of additional package bids at
the conclusion of the SACA phase
through a supplemental round of sealed
bidding. BOEM would then consider all
bid configurations from all the SACA
rounds and the supplemental round in
determining the winning set of lots
based on revenue maximization. Note
that any time BOEM proposes a sealed
bidding round, we would consider
using a ‘‘Second Price Rule,’’ in which
the winning bidder would only be
required to pay the amount bid by the
next highest bidder. This prevents a
winning bidder from paying more than
would have been necessary to win. The
Second Price Rule can also benefit the
government by discouraging ‘‘bid
shading.’’ This happens when a bidder
bids the amount the bidder thinks will
win instead of the amount the bidder
thinks the lot is worth, in order to avoid
overpaying.
• A third variant would use a nonclock ascending package auction format.
In this format, bidders would select
packages and also name the price they
would pay for those packages. In
contrast to the clock formats, bidders
would submit a price at or above the
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:04 Dec 05, 2011
Jkt 226001
minimum required bid increment for
their desired package in each round,
and the set of packages with the greatest
auction revenue would become
provisional winners at the end of each
round. The auction would end when
none of the bids change from one round
to the next. BOEM would examine all
the packages submitted and select the
packages that maximize revenue.
For each of the auction formats listed
above, BOEM would need to determine
what information is given to bidders at
the outset of each round of the auction.
For example, bidders could be informed
of the number of bids for each lot
submitted in the previous round.
Bidders in a clock auction (variations 1
and 2) would also be informed of the
announced price for each lot, while
bidders in a non-clock auction
(variation 3) would be informed of the
aggregate dollar amount of active high
bids.
Theoretical work, including the
contract study mentioned earlier,
indicates that a package clock auction
with a supplemental bidding round is
the most effective method for improving
auction efficiency. However, BOEM is
concerned about designing and using
this approach in initial sales, given its
reliance on complex bidding rules and
solution algorithms, in conjunction with
the need to prepare and publish these
complicated bidding rules in a
transparent manner.
Expanded details on both the clock
and non-clock options under
consideration are available on BOEM’s
web site, and we encourage comments
on the more complicated package
auction alternatives and their
appropriateness in early auctions. Refer
to Section 6 in Ausubel and Cramton
(2011a) for an overview of clock
auctions and Section 5.3 in Ausubel and
Cramton (2011c) for a comparison of the
package clock approaches with
examples and further explanation of the
rules.
Multiple Factor Auctions
The auction formats described above
in this notice are considered sufficient
to meet the agency’s needs in a wide
variety of contexts. However, in certain
limited circumstances, BOEM may
determine that other factors, along with
cash bids, should be considered in
determining how it issues leases and,
indirectly, how much winning bidders
should pay. For example, as BOEM
noted in publishing its regulations in
2009:
[D]uring the time that [BOEM] has been
promulgating this rule, the States of
Delaware, New Jersey, and Rhode Island have
conducted competitive processes and have
PO 00000
Frm 00057
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
selected companies to develop wind
resources on the OCS. We believe that the
pre-existing State processes are relevant to
the competitive processes that [BOEM] is
required to conduct following approval of
this rule. We intend to do so by using a
competitive process that considers, among
other things, whether a prospective lessee
has a power purchase agreement or is the
certified winner of a competitive process
conducted by an adjacent State.
74 FR 19,663 (Apr. 29, 2009). Therefore,
in certain circumstances, BOEM will
consider holding ‘‘Multiple Factor
Auctions,’’ in which non-financial
considerations are taken into account at
the outset.
If BOEM decides to employ such an
auction format, it proposes to do so in
a two-phase auction: A non-monetary
phase, followed by a second phase using
one of the standard auction formats
described above. Prior to the auction,
BOEM would announce the nonmonetary factors to be considered, and
the value assigned to each factor. To
ensure a fair and transparent process
and to ease the task of implementing the
auction, BOEM would use a limited
number of objective, ‘‘yes-no’’ factors.
Examples of such factors could include:
• Do you currently hold a firm
financial commitment for the sale of at
least 100 MW of power from a proposed
offshore wind development in the lease
sale area in the form of either a firm
purchase power agreement (PPA) that
has been approved by the state utility
commission or its equivalent OR an
ocean renewable energy credit approved
by the appropriate state agency?
• Have you completed installation of
a meteorological measurement tower on
a BOEM limited lease located within the
lease sale area?
Each factor would be assigned a
percent discount to be applied against
the amount that winning bidders would
be required to pay BOEM following the
auction. Between the non-monetary
phase and the monetary phase, each
bidder would be informed of the total
discount for which it qualifies. To
encourage competition and balance nonfinancial and financial bidding factors
in the auction, BOEM is not likely to
offer a bidder a discount of more than
25 percent on the basis of non-monetary
factors. Refer to Ausubel and Cramton
(2011b) and Sections 3 and 4 in Ausubel
and Cramton (2011c) for further
evaluation of multiple-factor
approaches.
Comments and Responses Requested
BOEM is requesting that the public
and any interested or affected parties
provide specific and detailed comments
regarding the auction format
E:\FR\FM\06DEN1.SGM
06DEN1
jlentini on DSK4TPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 234 / Tuesday, December 6, 2011 / Notices
recommendations described herein and
in the supporting materials. In addition,
BOEM is providing the following list of
questions to which it is seeking
substantive responses, including
rationales and explanations for the
answers provided.
1. How should we configure and size
auction lots? Should lots generally
correspond to an OCS block? What
characteristics should BOEM take into
account when sub-dividing a wind
energy area into lots represented by OCS
blocks or by OCS blocks grouped into
zones or project areas? Refer to Sections
6.1.1 and 7.1 in Ausubel and Cramton
(2011c) for discussions of lot
designation.
2. Should the lots auctioned to a
single bidder consist of contiguous OCS
blocks? Refer to Section 6.2.9 in
Ausubel and Cramton (2011c) for a
discussion of the contiguous lots rule.
3. Should each bidding entity be
limited to bidding on a single
contiguous set of blocks?
4. What restrictions should be placed
on bidders seeking more than one
package of lots during an auction?
5. What factors contribute to the size
of an area needed to support an
economically viable offshore wind
energy facility? Should there be an
established rule-of-thumb used to
determine the minimum and maximum
number of OCS blocks needed? Refer to
Section 4.4 in Ausubel and Cramton
(2011c) for a discussion of competition
constraints.
6. At what asking price per block or
per acre should BOEM commence the
auction? In other words, what is an
appropriate minimum bid per block? At
what minimum asking price would you
consider not participating in the
auction? Refer to Section 6.2.6 in
Ausubel and Cramton (2011c) for a
discussion of reserve pricing.
7. Which of the auction formats
discussed and referenced in this notice
do you prefer BOEM use? Does your
answer differ by location? Which
features of the auction formats would
you like to see modified or eliminated?
8. Do the concerns associated with a
SACA format (e.g., undersell) justify the
added complexity of a package auction?
Refer to Section 5.3 in Ausubel and
Cramton (2011c) for an example of how
undersell occurs.
9. BOEM is considering using a
‘‘second-pricing rule’’ in certain specific
contexts, including any auction that
includes a sealed-bid phase. How
important is it to you that the auction
format includes such a second-pricing
rule? Would you offer your maximum
value as a bid for all lots of interest
under a second-price auction
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:04 Dec 05, 2011
Jkt 226001
formulation? Refer to Section 5.3.11 in
Ausubel and Cramton (2011c) for a
discussion of winning price
determination.
10. What aspects of the auction
formats discussed in this note concern
you the most? Which features would
you like to see retained in practice?
11. What additional factors should
BOEM consider in a multiple factor
auction beyond those enumerated in
this Information Request? How should
all of these factors be weighted? Refer to
Section 4.1.3 in Ausubel and Cramton
(2011b) and Section 3.2 in Ausubel and
Cramton (2011c) for a discussion of
factor design and weighting.
12. Should lots in desirable locations
be weighted differently than those of
equal size in less desirable locations?
Would this potentially affect your level
of activity during the auction? For
example, BOEM could adjust rules such
that a bidder could expand the number
of lots bid on if those lots are in an area
that BOEM had determined is less
desirable. This is described further in
the materials available on BOEM’s Web
site. Refer to Sections 5.3.8 and 6.2.7 in
Ausubel and Cramton (2011c) for
discussion of such rules.
13. Are there auction formats not
included in this Information Request
that BOEM should consider?
Please provide responses to the above
questions, and/or any comments or
suggestions on the auction formats and
activity rules discussed in this
Information Request and referenced in
the material at BOEM’s Web site at
https://www.boem.gov/RenewableEnergy-Program/RegulatoryInformation/Renewable-Energy-AuctionFormats.aspx.
References
Ausubel, Lawrence M. and Peter Cramton
(2011a) ‘‘Auction Design for Wind
Rights,’’ Report to Bureau of Ocean
Energy Management.
Ausubel, Lawrence M. and Peter Cramton
(2011b) ‘‘Multiple-Factor Auction Design
for Wind Rights,’’ Report to Bureau of
Ocean Energy Management.
Ausubel, Lawrence M. and Peter Cramton
(2011c) ‘‘Comparision of Auction
Formats for Auctioning Wind Rights,’’
Report to Bureau of Ocean Energy
Management.
Dated: November 28, 2011.
Tommy P. Beaudreau,
Director, Bureau of Ocean Energy
Management.
[FR Doc. 2011–31222 Filed 12–1–11; 4:15 pm]
BILLING CODE 4310–MR–P
PO 00000
Frm 00058
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
76177
DEPARTMENT OF THE INTERIOR
U.S. Geological Survey
[USGS–GX12RN000DSA200]
Agency Information Collection
Activities: Comment Request
U.S. Geological Survey (USGS),
Interior.
ACTION: Notice of an extension of an
information collection (1028–0048).
AGENCY:
We (the U.S. Geological
Survey) will ask the Office of
Management and Budget (OMB) to
approve the information collection (IC)
described below. As required by the
Paperwork Reduction Act (PRA) of
1995, and as part of our continuing
efforts to reduce paperwork and
respondent burden, we invite the
general public and other Federal
agencies to take this opportunity to
comment on this IC. This IC is
scheduled to expire on March 31, 2012.
DATES: You must submit comments on
or before February 6, 2012.
ADDRESSES: Please submit a copy of
your comments to the Information
Collections Clearance Officer, U.S.
Geological Survey, 12201 Sunrise Valley
Drive MS 807, Reston, VA 20192 (mail);
(703) 648–7199 (fax); or
smbaloch@usgs.gov (email). Use
Information Collection Number 1028–
0048 in the subject line.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: To
request additional information about
this IC, contact Jim Dewey at (303) 274–
8419.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION:
SUMMARY:
I. Abstract
The U.S. Geological Survey is
required to collect, evaluate, publish
and distribute publish information
concerning earthquakes. Respondents
will have an opportunity to voluntarily
supply information concerning the
effects of shaking from an earthquake—
on themselves, buildings, other manmade structures, and ground effects
such as faulting or landslides.
We will protect information from
respondents considered proprietary
under the Freedom of Information Act
(5 U.S.C. 552) and implementing
regulations (43 CFR part 2), and under
regulations at 30 CFR 250.197, ‘‘Data
and information to be made available to
the public or for limited inspection.’’
Responses are voluntary. No questions
of a ‘‘sensitive’’ nature are asked. We
will release data collected on these
forms only in formats that do not
include proprietary information
volunteered by respondents.
E:\FR\FM\06DEN1.SGM
06DEN1
Agencies
[Federal Register Volume 76, Number 234 (Tuesday, December 6, 2011)]
[Notices]
[Pages 76174-76177]
From the Federal Register Online via the Government Printing Office [www.gpo.gov]
[FR Doc No: 2011-31222]
=======================================================================
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
DEPARTMENT OF THE INTERIOR
Bureau of Ocean Energy Management
[Docket BOEM-2011-0095]
Request for Information on the State of the Offshore Renewable
Energy Industry--Auction Format Information Request (AFIR)
AGENCY: Bureau of Ocean Energy Management (BOEM), Interior.
ACTION: Request for information.
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
SUMMARY: BOEM invites public comment on a proposed set of auction
formats which may be used to issue commercial renewable energy leases
on the Outer Continental Shelf (OCS). BOEM is examining several auction
formats, each designed to efficiently issue renewable energy leases to
those who value them most and are best positioned to develop them,
while also ensuring that the government receives a fair return in
exchange. BOEM is focusing primarily on variations of Ascending Clock
Auctions and Package Auctions formats described in more detail below.
BOEM is also considering a multiple factor auction approach in which
bidders can earn a discount on their bids submitted under one of the
auction formats noted above, based on company-specific attributes
deemed relevant to the success of their projects. The auction format
selected for each sale area would likely vary based on the actual
characteristics of that sale. Such characteristics could include the
size and homogeneity of the area to be offered. BOEM will hold a
workshop to help familiarize stakeholders with the auction format
options and to solicit feedback on Friday, December 16, 2011, at the
South Interior Building in Washington, DC.
DATES: Comments should be submitted electronically or postmarked no
later than January 20, 2012. All written comments received during the
comment period will be made available to the public and considered
during preparation of Proposed Sale Notices (PSN) pertaining to the
competitive leasing of OCS lands to support the development of offshore
wind energy resources.
ADDRESSES: Potential auction participants, Federal, state, and local
government agencies, tribal governments, and other interested parties
are requested to submit their written comments on the contents of this
AFIR in one of the following ways:
1. Electronically: https://www.regulations.gov. In the entry titled
``Enter Keyword or ID,'' enter BOEM-2011-0095 then click ``search.''
Follow the instructions to submit public comments and view supporting
and related materials available for this document.
2. Written Comments: In written form, delivered by hand or by mail,
enclosed in an envelope labeled ``Comments on Offshore Wind AFIR'' to:
Economics Division, Bureau of Ocean Energy Management, 381 Elden
Street, MS 4050, Herndon, Virginia 20170-4817.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: Greg Adams, BOEM Economics Division,
381 Elden Street, MS 4050, Herndon, Virginia 20170-4817, (703) 787-1537
or greg.adams@boem.gov; or Wright Frank, BOEM Office of Renewable
Energy Programs, 381 Elden Street, HM 1328, Herndon, Virginia 20170,
(703) 787-1325 or wright.frank@boem.gov.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION:
Authority
This request for information is published pursuant to subsection
8(p) of the OCS Lands Act (43 U.S.C. 1337(p)), as amended by section
388 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 (EPAct) and the implementing
regulations at 30 CFR 585.116, which authorize the Director of BOEM to
solicit information from industry and other relevant stakeholders to
evaluate the state of the offshore renewable energy industry, including
economic matters that promote or detract from continued development.
The information received may be used to evaluate program options to
promote safe and environmentally responsible development in a manner
that ensures a fair value for use of the nation's OCS.
Purpose of the AFIR
The purpose of this information request is to invite public comment
on the auction format options described in this request. Due to the
complexities associated with lease valuation and optimal lease
configurations, renewable energy leasing will require more diverse
approaches than the sealed-bid, cash bonus approach used to issue
offshore oil and gas leases.
The auction formats and their specifications are designed to
address important program objectives, including:
Fair Return: BOEM is statutorily required to obtain a
``fair return'' for leases and grants on the OCS;
Economic Efficiency: The lease auction process should try
to ensure that commercial renewable energy leases on the OCS are
awarded to those who value the areas the most;
Program Efficiency: The lease auction process must be
manageable for BOEM to administer;
Lease Boundary Flexibility: Within constraints fixed by
BOEM, the auction should allow bidders to identify the optimal lease
areas;
Competition: The lease auction process must be fair, and
encourage participation from all interested bidders;
Transparency: The lease auction process must be an open
one in which bids are comparable and the reason why the winners won is
clear;
Neutrality: The lease auction process must ensure that all
bidders are treated equally;
Simplicity: The lease auction process must be easily
understood and implemented, by both the bidders and BOEM; and
Consistency: The lease auction process should be
applicable to the issuance of leases in a variety of potential
renewable energy development contexts.
BOEM contracted with Power Auctions LLC to study auction formats
for issuing renewable energy leases (hereinafter, ``Ausubel and Cramton
(2011a), (2011b), and (2011c),'' respectively). Based on its findings
and BOEM's own internal research, BOEM has identified several
potentially suitable auction formats. A more comprehensive discussion
of these auction formats prepared by BOEM staff, along with the Power
Auctions LLC study, can be found on BOEM's
[[Page 76175]]
Web site at https://www.boem.gov/Renewable-Energy-Program/Regulatory-Information/Renewable-Energy-Auction-Formats.aspx.
Preference for Bidding on the Cash Bonus
Although BOEM has the authority to conduct an auction with either
the cash bonus or operating fee rate as the bid variable, the bureau
generally prefers using the cash bonus. Conducting an auction with the
bonus bid as the variable has a number of benefits. It allows
straightforward comparison of competing offers and tends to award
leases to developers with good financial backing. Because the winning
bidders would need to pay the bonus bid before the lease is issued, it
prevents undercapitalized bidders from committing to a greater payment
than they can afford. Refer to Section 2.3 in Ausubel and Cramton
(2011a) for further discussion.
Single Lot Auctions: Simple Ascending Clock Auction Format
In a single lot auction, there is only one object of bidding
(``lot''), and the entire lease area would be auctioned off as a single
entity. BOEM could use a single lot auction in situations where it is
expected that only one lease would be practical for the available
acreage, because the area would not be large enough to support multiple
projects.
In a single lot auction utilizing an ascending clock auction
format, BOEM would set an initial asking price for the single lot, and
bidders would indicate whether or not they are interested in bidding
for that lot at that price. If BOEM received more than one bid, BOEM
would increase the asking price, which ``ticks'' up like a clock, until
only a single bidder is willing to meet the announced price. This
format enables price discovery by the bidders during the auction and
reduces the guesswork required for bidders to value offshore leases.
One complication of the simple ascending clock auction is that a
tie-breaking procedure is needed when all the remaining bidders drop
out in the same round. Exit bids are one practical way of solving this
problem in the single lot case. An exit bid allows bidders who are
unwilling to meet the next round's bid price to specify the maximum
price they would be willing to pay short of the new asking price. If
all remaining bidders drop out from one round to the next, the bidder
with the highest exit bid would prevail. Another tie-breaking procedure
would be for BOEM to incrementally reduce the current asking price
until one bidder bids. In either approach, if the tie persists after
the tie-breaking procedure, the winner could be determined based on a
random draw. Refer to Section 5.2 in Ausubel and Cramton (2011c) for
further discussion.
Multiple Lot Auctions: Simultaneous Ascending Clock Auction Format
In most lease sales, BOEM expects to issue multiple commercial
renewable energy leases in the same auction. In this case, BOEM is
considering the use of a Simultaneous Ascending Clock Auction (SACA).
In such a lease sale, BOEM would divide the entire area offered for
leasing into smaller lots which would be the objects of the bidding. To
form the lots, BOEM would likely use OCS lease blocks (approximately 3
statute miles by 3 statute miles), aliquots (squares 1/16th that size),
or some combination of these. The auction would enable bidding on all
of the lots simultaneously.
BOEM would set a minimum asking price for each lot. Bidders would
bid on the combination of lots they are interested in at that price.
The bid price set by BOEM for contested lots (those receiving two or
more bids) would increase in the next round, while the price for
uncontested lots (those receiving zero or one bid) would remain the
same in the next round. BOEM would publish the announced prices and the
number of bids on each lot at the outset of each round in the auction.
A lot which is uncontested through several rounds may become
contested because, as the auction proceeds, a bidder can shift its
bids, for example, from a contested lot to an uncontested lot. If a
bidder submits the only bid on a particular lot, the standing price for
that lot remains unchanged through subsequent rounds until an
additional bid is submitted on that lot at the standing bid price, or
the auction ends. As soon as an uncontested lot receives more than one
bid, it is treated as a contested lot.
If any bidder finds that it has submitted a bid on a contested lot,
in the next round that bidder can either:
Meet the new asking price for this lot;
Drop its bid for this lot and submit a new bid elsewhere;
or
Drop its bid for this lot and not submit a new bid
elsewhere.
The auction ends when no lot has more than one bid at the last-
announced asking price set by BOEM. Because any bidder can move a bid
from a contested lot to another lot, the auction for any particular lot
is not over until bidding has concluded for all lots. The winning
bidders are those with active bids in the final round and they are
obligated to pay the final round prices for the lots they win.
Bidding in a SACA auction must comply with a set of rules that BOEM
will include in the Proposed and Final Sale Notices. For example:
A bidder may only bid on contiguous lots to form a single
lease.
Bidders who want to acquire multiple lease areas must
register for the auction as separate bidding entities.
Bidders may maintain or reduce the number of lots they bid
on from one round to the next; but they may not increase the number of
lots they bid on from one round to the next. This helps to control
certain opportunities for gaming, and drives the auction towards a
timely conclusion.
A ``bid eligibility rule'' would determine the maximum
number of lots that a bidder is eligible to bid on in the auction in
the opening round, or in any subsequent round of the auction. Bidders'
eligibility is based on the amount of money posted as their bid
deposit. The maximum number of lots that a bidder may bid on equals the
maximum number of lots that would be covered by the bidder's deposit at
the opening bid price.
Bidders may submit an exit bid amount for a particular set
of lots in any round. An exit bid can only win if the auction ends in
that round, and there is no higher bid on any of the lots in the set.
If any of these conditions is not met, the bid is set aside and the
bidder exits the auction.
The SACA format provides an opportunity for price discovery like
the ascending clock auction format used to bid on a single item. Also,
the SACA format permits a bidder to identify combinations of lots which
support its particular plan for a commercial offshore wind energy
project. Refer to Section 5 in Ausubel and Cramton (2011a) for further
discussion of clock auctions and Section 5.3.5 in Ausubel and Cramton
(2011c) (Alternative I) for an example of how they work.
One potential problem with the SACA format arises when multiple
bidders who have submitted bids on the same lots simultaneously drop
out of the auction. In this situation, designing and implementing
tiebreaking rules becomes complex. Under the sample rules described
above, because bidders may not increase the number of lots on which
they bid from one round to the next, large and potentially high-value
areas in the auction area may go unclaimed (hereinafter,
``undersell''). The difficulty of designing effective exit bidding
rules for multiple lot auctions limits their potential effectiveness in
[[Page 76176]]
addressing undersell. As a result, it may be a challenge to fully
achieve program goals such as optimal configuration of the winning sets
of packages and ensuring receipt of fair value with the SACA format.
Alternative for Multiple Lot Auctions: Package Auctions
Several variations of the package auction format merit
consideration for leasing packages of lots for offshore development of
electricity from wind resources. Below are brief outlines of three such
package auction variants. More detailed descriptions of these auction
formats are available on BOEM's web site. A ``package'' is the
arrangement of lots that a given bidder has selected in a given round
of bidding paired with the price the bidder is willing to pay in that
round for that arrangement of lots.
One variant is a single-phase package clock auction where
the bidding would proceed just like a SACA. However, BOEM could select
the best arrangement of packages from earlier rounds of the auction to
maximize seller revenue, perhaps subject to the condition that the
prevailing bids in the final round are included in the winning set of
lots. If the SACA phase of bidding resulted in a significant undersell,
BOEM could revive early round bids to ``fill in'' undersold areas.
A second variant builds on the first variation, but allows
bidders to add a number of additional package bids at the conclusion of
the SACA phase through a supplemental round of sealed bidding. BOEM
would then consider all bid configurations from all the SACA rounds and
the supplemental round in determining the winning set of lots based on
revenue maximization. Note that any time BOEM proposes a sealed bidding
round, we would consider using a ``Second Price Rule,'' in which the
winning bidder would only be required to pay the amount bid by the next
highest bidder. This prevents a winning bidder from paying more than
would have been necessary to win. The Second Price Rule can also
benefit the government by discouraging ``bid shading.'' This happens
when a bidder bids the amount the bidder thinks will win instead of the
amount the bidder thinks the lot is worth, in order to avoid
overpaying.
A third variant would use a non-clock ascending package
auction format. In this format, bidders would select packages and also
name the price they would pay for those packages. In contrast to the
clock formats, bidders would submit a price at or above the minimum
required bid increment for their desired package in each round, and the
set of packages with the greatest auction revenue would become
provisional winners at the end of each round. The auction would end
when none of the bids change from one round to the next. BOEM would
examine all the packages submitted and select the packages that
maximize revenue.
For each of the auction formats listed above, BOEM would need to
determine what information is given to bidders at the outset of each
round of the auction. For example, bidders could be informed of the
number of bids for each lot submitted in the previous round. Bidders in
a clock auction (variations 1 and 2) would also be informed of the
announced price for each lot, while bidders in a non-clock auction
(variation 3) would be informed of the aggregate dollar amount of
active high bids.
Theoretical work, including the contract study mentioned earlier,
indicates that a package clock auction with a supplemental bidding
round is the most effective method for improving auction efficiency.
However, BOEM is concerned about designing and using this approach in
initial sales, given its reliance on complex bidding rules and solution
algorithms, in conjunction with the need to prepare and publish these
complicated bidding rules in a transparent manner.
Expanded details on both the clock and non-clock options under
consideration are available on BOEM's web site, and we encourage
comments on the more complicated package auction alternatives and their
appropriateness in early auctions. Refer to Section 6 in Ausubel and
Cramton (2011a) for an overview of clock auctions and Section 5.3 in
Ausubel and Cramton (2011c) for a comparison of the package clock
approaches with examples and further explanation of the rules.
Multiple Factor Auctions
The auction formats described above in this notice are considered
sufficient to meet the agency's needs in a wide variety of contexts.
However, in certain limited circumstances, BOEM may determine that
other factors, along with cash bids, should be considered in
determining how it issues leases and, indirectly, how much winning
bidders should pay. For example, as BOEM noted in publishing its
regulations in 2009:
[D]uring the time that [BOEM] has been promulgating this rule,
the States of Delaware, New Jersey, and Rhode Island have conducted
competitive processes and have selected companies to develop wind
resources on the OCS. We believe that the pre-existing State
processes are relevant to the competitive processes that [BOEM] is
required to conduct following approval of this rule. We intend to do
so by using a competitive process that considers, among other
things, whether a prospective lessee has a power purchase agreement
or is the certified winner of a competitive process conducted by an
adjacent State.
74 FR 19,663 (Apr. 29, 2009). Therefore, in certain circumstances, BOEM
will consider holding ``Multiple Factor Auctions,'' in which non-
financial considerations are taken into account at the outset.
If BOEM decides to employ such an auction format, it proposes to do
so in a two-phase auction: A non-monetary phase, followed by a second
phase using one of the standard auction formats described above. Prior
to the auction, BOEM would announce the non-monetary factors to be
considered, and the value assigned to each factor. To ensure a fair and
transparent process and to ease the task of implementing the auction,
BOEM would use a limited number of objective, ``yes-no'' factors.
Examples of such factors could include:
Do you currently hold a firm financial commitment for the
sale of at least 100 MW of power from a proposed offshore wind
development in the lease sale area in the form of either a firm
purchase power agreement (PPA) that has been approved by the state
utility commission or its equivalent OR an ocean renewable energy
credit approved by the appropriate state agency?
Have you completed installation of a meteorological
measurement tower on a BOEM limited lease located within the lease sale
area?
Each factor would be assigned a percent discount to be applied
against the amount that winning bidders would be required to pay BOEM
following the auction. Between the non-monetary phase and the monetary
phase, each bidder would be informed of the total discount for which it
qualifies. To encourage competition and balance non-financial and
financial bidding factors in the auction, BOEM is not likely to offer a
bidder a discount of more than 25 percent on the basis of non-monetary
factors. Refer to Ausubel and Cramton (2011b) and Sections 3 and 4 in
Ausubel and Cramton (2011c) for further evaluation of multiple-factor
approaches.
Comments and Responses Requested
BOEM is requesting that the public and any interested or affected
parties provide specific and detailed comments regarding the auction
format
[[Page 76177]]
recommendations described herein and in the supporting materials. In
addition, BOEM is providing the following list of questions to which it
is seeking substantive responses, including rationales and explanations
for the answers provided.
1. How should we configure and size auction lots? Should lots
generally correspond to an OCS block? What characteristics should BOEM
take into account when sub-dividing a wind energy area into lots
represented by OCS blocks or by OCS blocks grouped into zones or
project areas? Refer to Sections 6.1.1 and 7.1 in Ausubel and Cramton
(2011c) for discussions of lot designation.
2. Should the lots auctioned to a single bidder consist of
contiguous OCS blocks? Refer to Section 6.2.9 in Ausubel and Cramton
(2011c) for a discussion of the contiguous lots rule.
3. Should each bidding entity be limited to bidding on a single
contiguous set of blocks?
4. What restrictions should be placed on bidders seeking more than
one package of lots during an auction?
5. What factors contribute to the size of an area needed to support
an economically viable offshore wind energy facility? Should there be
an established rule-of-thumb used to determine the minimum and maximum
number of OCS blocks needed? Refer to Section 4.4 in Ausubel and
Cramton (2011c) for a discussion of competition constraints.
6. At what asking price per block or per acre should BOEM commence
the auction? In other words, what is an appropriate minimum bid per
block? At what minimum asking price would you consider not
participating in the auction? Refer to Section 6.2.6 in Ausubel and
Cramton (2011c) for a discussion of reserve pricing.
7. Which of the auction formats discussed and referenced in this
notice do you prefer BOEM use? Does your answer differ by location?
Which features of the auction formats would you like to see modified or
eliminated?
8. Do the concerns associated with a SACA format (e.g., undersell)
justify the added complexity of a package auction? Refer to Section 5.3
in Ausubel and Cramton (2011c) for an example of how undersell occurs.
9. BOEM is considering using a ``second-pricing rule'' in certain
specific contexts, including any auction that includes a sealed-bid
phase. How important is it to you that the auction format includes such
a second-pricing rule? Would you offer your maximum value as a bid for
all lots of interest under a second-price auction formulation? Refer to
Section 5.3.11 in Ausubel and Cramton (2011c) for a discussion of
winning price determination.
10. What aspects of the auction formats discussed in this note
concern you the most? Which features would you like to see retained in
practice?
11. What additional factors should BOEM consider in a multiple
factor auction beyond those enumerated in this Information Request? How
should all of these factors be weighted? Refer to Section 4.1.3 in
Ausubel and Cramton (2011b) and Section 3.2 in Ausubel and Cramton
(2011c) for a discussion of factor design and weighting.
12. Should lots in desirable locations be weighted differently than
those of equal size in less desirable locations? Would this potentially
affect your level of activity during the auction? For example, BOEM
could adjust rules such that a bidder could expand the number of lots
bid on if those lots are in an area that BOEM had determined is less
desirable. This is described further in the materials available on
BOEM's Web site. Refer to Sections 5.3.8 and 6.2.7 in Ausubel and
Cramton (2011c) for discussion of such rules.
13. Are there auction formats not included in this Information
Request that BOEM should consider?
Please provide responses to the above questions, and/or any
comments or suggestions on the auction formats and activity rules
discussed in this Information Request and referenced in the material at
BOEM's Web site at https://www.boem.gov/Renewable-Energy-Program/Regulatory-Information/Renewable-Energy-Auction-Formats.aspx.
References
Ausubel, Lawrence M. and Peter Cramton (2011a) ``Auction Design for
Wind Rights,'' Report to Bureau of Ocean Energy Management.
Ausubel, Lawrence M. and Peter Cramton (2011b) ``Multiple-Factor
Auction Design for Wind Rights,'' Report to Bureau of Ocean Energy
Management.
Ausubel, Lawrence M. and Peter Cramton (2011c) ``Comparision of
Auction Formats for Auctioning Wind Rights,'' Report to Bureau of
Ocean Energy Management.
Dated: November 28, 2011.
Tommy P. Beaudreau,
Director, Bureau of Ocean Energy Management.
[FR Doc. 2011-31222 Filed 12-1-11; 4:15 pm]
BILLING CODE 4310-MR-P