Pool Corporation; Analysis To Aid Public Comment, 72923-72928 [2011-30435]
Download as PDF
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 228 / Monday, November 28, 2011 / Notices
set forth in paragraph 7 of the Act (12
U.S.C. 1817(j)(7)).
The notices are available for
immediate inspection at the Federal
Reserve Bank indicated. The notices
also will be available for inspection at
the offices of the Board of Governors.
Interested persons may express their
views in writing to the Reserve Bank
indicated for that notice or to the offices
of the Board of Governors. Comments
must be received not later than
December 12, 2011.
A. Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
(Nadine Wallman, Vice President) 1455
East Sixth Street, Cleveland, Ohio
44101–2566:
1. Timothy T. O’Dell IRA, Thad R.
Perry, Susanne G. Perry, Marie-Luise
Marx, and Richard M. Mershad, Trustee,
for the Richard M. Mershad Revocable
Trust, all of New Albany, Ohio; Robert
E. Hoeweler IRA, Paula Hoeweler IRA,
and Robert E. and Paula L. Hoeweler, all
of Cincinnati, Ohio; Donal H. Malenick
and Michael W. Lenhart, both of Naples,
Florida; James H. Frauenberg, II, George
K. Richards, Trustee of the George K.
Richards Trust, Deborah Phillips Bower,
MOCORP, LLC, Moberger LTD, and Ohio
Indemnity Company of Columbus, all of
Columbus, Ohio; Eric G. Leininger,
Upper Arlington, Ohio; Robert C.
Moberger, Dublin, Ohio; Dynalab, LLC,
Reynoldsburg, Ohio; and Pozzolana
Consulting, LLC, Gainesville, Florida; to
acquire voting shares of Central Federal
Corporation, and thereby indirectly
acquire voting share of CF Bank, both in
Fairlawn, Ohio.
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System, November 22, 2011.
Robert deV. Frierson,
Deputy Secretary of the Board.
[FR Doc. 2011–30483 Filed 11–25–11; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6210–01–P
pmangrum on DSK3VPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
Formations of, Acquisitions by, and
Mergers of Bank Holding Companies;
Correction
This notice corrects a notice (FR Doc.
11–30105) published on page 72206 of
the issue for Tuesday, November 22,
2011.
Under the Federal Reserve Bank of
San Francisco heading, the entry for
American Start-Up Financial
Institutions Investments, I, L.P., and
CKH Capital, Inc., both in Monterey
Park, California, is revised to read as
follows:
A. Federal Reserve Bank of San
Francisco (Kenneth Binning, Vice
President, Applications and
15:34 Nov 25, 2011
Jkt 226001
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System, November 22, 2011.
Robert deV. Frierson,
Deputy Secretary of the Board.
[FR Doc. 2011–30482 Filed 11–25–11; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6210–01–P
FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION
[File No. 101 0115]
Pool Corporation; Analysis To Aid
Public Comment
Federal Trade Commission.
Proposed consent agreement.
AGENCY:
ACTION:
The consent agreement in this
matter settles alleged violations of
federal law prohibiting unfair or
deceptive acts or practices or unfair
methods of competition. The attached
Analysis to Aid Public Comment
describes both the allegations in the
draft complaint and the terms of the
consent order—embodied in the consent
agreement—that would settle these
allegations.
SUMMARY:
Comments must be received on
or before December 22, 2011.
ADDRESSES: Interested parties may file a
comment online or on paper, by
following the instructions in the
Request for Comment part of the
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION section
below. Write ‘‘PoolCorp, File No. 101
0115’’ on your comment, and file your
comment online at https://
ftcpublic.commentworks.com/ftc/
poolcorpconsent, by following the
instructions on the Web-based form. If
you prefer to file your comment on
paper, mail or deliver your comment to
the following address: Federal Trade
Commission, Office of the Secretary,
Room H–113 (Annex D), 600
Pennsylvania Avenue NW., Washington,
DC 20580.
DATES:
FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM
VerDate Mar<15>2010
Enforcement) 101 Market Street, San
Francisco, California 94105–1579:
1. America Start-Up Financial
Institutions Investments, I, L.P., and
CKH Capital, Inc., both in Monterey
Park, California; to become bank
holding companies by acquiring up to
62 percent of the voting shares of New
Omni Bank, National Association,
Alhambra, California.
In connection with this application,
Applicants also have applied to retain
5.9 percent interest of the voting shares
of First PacTrust Bancorp, Inc., and
thereby indirectly retain Pacific Trust
Bank, both in Chula Vista, California,
and engage in operating as savings and
loan association, pursuant to section
225.28(b)(4)(ii) of Regulation Y.
PO 00000
Frm 00027
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
72923
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
Linda Holleran (202) 326–2267, FTC,
Bureau of Competition, 600
Pennsylvania Avenue NW., Washington,
DC 20580.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: Pursuant
to section 6(f) of the Federal Trade
Commission Act, 38 Stat. 721, 15 U.S.C.
46(f), and § 2.34 of the Commission’s
Rules of Practice, 16 CFR 2.34, notice is
hereby given that the above-captioned
consent agreement containing a consent
order to cease and desist, having been
filed with and accepted, subject to final
approval, by the Commission, has been
placed on the public record for a period
of thirty (30) days. The following
Analysis to Aid Public Comment
describes the terms of the consent
agreement, and the allegations in the
complaint. An electronic copy of the
full text of the consent agreement
package can be obtained from the FTC
Home Page (for November 21, 2011), on
the World Wide Web, at https://
www.ftc.gov/os/actions.shtm. A paper
copy can be obtained from the FTC
Public Reference Room, Room 130–H,
600 Pennsylvania Avenue NW.,
Washington, DC 20580, either in person
or by calling (202) 326–2222.
You can file a comment online or on
paper. For the Commission to consider
your comment, we must receive it on or
before December 22, 2011. Write
‘‘PoolCorp, File No. 101 0115’’ on your
comment. Your comment—including
your name and your state—will be
placed on the public record of this
proceeding, including, to the extent
practicable, on the public Commission
Web site, at https://www.ftc.gov/os/
publiccomments.shtm. As a matter of
discretion, the Commission tries to
remove individuals’ home contact
information from comments before
placing them on the Commission Web
site.
Because your comment will be made
public, you are solely responsible for
making sure that your comment does
not include any sensitive personal
information, like anyone’s Social
Security number, date of birth, driver’s
license number or other state
identification number or foreign country
equivalent, passport number, financial
account number, or credit or debit card
number. You are also solely responsible
for making sure that your comment does
not include any sensitive health
information, like medical records or
other individually identifiable health
information. In addition, do not include
any ‘‘[t]rade secret or any commercial or
financial information which is obtained
from any person and which is privileged
or confidential,’’ as provided in Section
E:\FR\FM\28NON1.SGM
28NON1
pmangrum on DSK3VPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
72924
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 228 / Monday, November 28, 2011 / Notices
6(f) of the FTC Act, 15 U.S.C. 46(f), and
FTC Rule 4.10(a)(2), 16 CFR 4.10(a)(2).
In particular, do not include
competitively sensitive information
such as costs, sales statistics,
inventories, formulas, patterns, devices,
manufacturing processes, or customer
names.
If you want the Commission to give
your comment confidential treatment,
you must file it in paper form, with a
request for confidential treatment, and
you have to follow the procedure
explained in FTC Rule 4.9(c), 16 CFR
4.9(c).1 Your comment will be kept
confidential only if the FTC General
Counsel, in his or her sole discretion,
grants your request in accordance with
the law and the public interest.
Postal mail addressed to the
Commission is subject to delay due to
heightened security screening. As a
result, we encourage you to submit your
comments online. To make sure that the
Commission considers your online
comment, you must file it at https://
ftcpublic.commentworks.com/ftc/
poolcorpconsent by following the
instructions on the web-based form. If
this Notice appears at https://
www.regulations.gov/#!home, you also
may file a comment through that Web
site.
If you file your comment on paper,
write ‘‘PoolCorp, File No. 101 0115’’ on
your comment and on the envelope, and
mail or deliver it to the following
address: Federal Trade Commission,
Office of the Secretary, Room H–113
(Annex D), 600 Pennsylvania Avenue
NW., Washington, DC 20580. If possible,
submit your paper comment to the
Commission by courier or overnight
service.
Visit the Commission Web site at
https://www.ftc.gov to read this Notice
and the news release describing it. The
FTC Act and other laws that the
Commission administers permit the
collection of public comments to
consider and use in this proceeding as
appropriate. The Commission will
consider all timely and responsive
public comments that it receives on or
before December 22, 2011. You can find
more information, including routine
uses permitted by the Privacy Act, in
the Commission’s privacy policy, at
https://www.ftc.gov/ftc/privacy.htm.
1 In particular, the written request for confidential
treatment that accompanies the comment must
include the factual and legal basis for the request,
and must identify the specific portions of the
comment to be withheld from the public record. See
FTC Rule 4.9(c), 16 CFR 4.9(c).
VerDate Mar<15>2010
15:34 Nov 25, 2011
Jkt 226001
Analysis of Agreement Containing
Consent Order To Aid Public Comment
The Federal Trade Commission has
accepted for public comment an
Agreement Containing Consent Order to
Cease and Desist (‘‘Agreement’’) with
Pool Corporation (‘‘PoolCorp’’).
PoolCorp is the world’s largest
distributor of products used in the
construction, renovation, repair, service,
and maintenance of residential and
commercial swimming pools. The
Agreement resolves charges that
PoolCorp used exclusionary acts and
practices to maintain its monopoly
power in the pool product distribution
market in violation of Section 5 of the
Federal Trade Commission Act, 15
U.S.C. 45.
The administrative complaint that
accompanies the Agreement
(‘‘Complaint’’) alleges that PoolCorp
used its monopoly power in local
geographic markets to prevent
manufacturers from supplying pool
products to new entrants since at least
2003. As a result, PoolCorp foreclosed
rival distributors from obtaining pool
products—a necessary input to
compete—and significantly raised its
rivals’ costs, thereby lowering output,
increasing prices, and diminishing
consumer choice.
The Commission anticipates that the
competitive issues described in the
Complaint will be resolved by accepting
the proposed Order, subject to final
approval, contained in the Agreement.
The Agreement has been placed on the
public record for 30 days for receipt of
comments from interested members of
the public. Comments received during
this period will become part of the
public record. After 30 days, the
Commission will again review the
Agreement and comments received, and
will decide whether it should withdraw
from the Agreement or make final the
Order contained in the Agreement.
The purpose of this Analysis to Aid
Public Comment is to invite and
facilitate public comment concerning
the proposed Order. It is not intended
to constitute an official interpretation of
the Agreement and proposed Order or in
any way to modify their terms.
The Agreement is for settlement
purposes only and does not constitute
an admission by PoolCorp that the law
has been violated as alleged in the
Complaint or that the facts alleged in
the Complaint, other than jurisdictional
facts, are true.
I. The Complaint
The Complaint makes the following
allegations.
PO 00000
Frm 00028
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
A. Industry Background
This case involves wholesale
distribution in the swimming pool
industry. There are over nine million
residential pools in the United States,
and over 250,000 commercial pools
operated by hotels, country clubs,
apartment buildings, municipalities,
and others. In 2010, the distribution of
pool products was an estimated $3
billion industry in the United States.
Manufacturers use distributors to sell
the products used to build, repair,
service, and maintain residential and
commercial swimming pools (‘‘pool
products’’). Pool products include,
among others, pumps, filters, heaters,
covers, cleaners, diving boards, steps,
rails, pool liners, pool walls, and the
parts necessary to maintain pool
equipment. Distributors purchase pool
products from manufacturers,
warehouse them, and then resell the
products to pool retail stores, pool
service companies and pool builders
(collectively, ‘‘pool dealers’’ or
‘‘dealers’’). Dealers, in turn, sell the pool
products to the ultimate consumer:
owners of residential and commercial
swimming pools. The swimming pool
industry is very fragmented and
wholesale distributors make it more
efficient for manufacturers and dealers
to sell their products. Distributors
purchase most, if not all, brands of pool
products that are produced by
manufacturers so that they can provide
convenient one-stop shopping for their
dealer customers. Distributors also
extend credit and provide quick
delivery of pool products to thousands
of dealers. The vast majority of dealers
are mom-and-pop operations that are
too small to buy directly from
manufacturers; for these dealers,
distributors are their only source of pool
products. Distributors also allow
manufacturers to operate their factories
year-round by purchasing large
quantities of pool products throughout
the year, even though the pool industry
is seasonal.
In general, manufacturers are willing
to sell their products to any creditworthy distributor that has a physical
warehouse and personnel with
knowledge of the pool industry.
Manufacturers typically prefer to have
two or more distributors selling their
products in a local geographic market in
order to ensure that the distributors
compete and give competitive service
and prices to their dealer customers.
To compete effectively as a
distributor, a firm must be able to buy
pool products directly from
manufacturers. There are no costeffective alternatives. While there are
E:\FR\FM\28NON1.SGM
28NON1
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 228 / Monday, November 28, 2011 / Notices
over 100 manufacturers of pool
products, there are only three full-line
manufacturers that produce almost all of
the products used to operate or repair
swimming pools: Pentair Water Pool &
Spa; Zodiac Pool Systems, Inc.; and
Hayward Pool Products. Collectively,
these manufacturers represent more
than 50 percent of all pool product
sales. To be successful, a distributor
must sell the products of at least one of
these manufacturers. As recognized by
PoolCorp, a positive relationship with
these and other manufacturers is
‘‘critical’’ to the success of a distributor.
B. PoolCorp’s Monopoly Power
The relevant market is no broader
than the wholesale distribution of pool
products in the United States and
numerous local geographic markets.
With the exception of large national
retail chains that purchase pool
products for their retail centers located
throughout the United States,
competition among distributors for sales
to dealers occurs locally. PoolCorp has
monopoly power in numerous local
markets, as evidenced by a persistently
high market share of 80 percent or more
for the past five years. PoolCorp’s
conduct of foreclosing new distributor
entrants from obtaining pool products
directly from manufacturers represents a
significant barrier to entry.
pmangrum on DSK3VPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
C. PoolCorp’s Conduct
Beginning in 2003 and continuing to
today, PoolCorp has implemented an
exclusionary policy that effectively
impeded entry by new distributors by
preventing them from being able to
purchase pool products directly from
manufacturers. Specifically, when a
new distributor attempted to enter a
local geographic market, PoolCorp
threatened manufacturers that it would
not deal with them if they also supplied
the new entrant. PoolCorp threatened to
terminate the purchase and sale of the
manufacturer’s pool products for all
200+ PoolCorp distribution centers
located throughout the United States.
PoolCorp’s policy did not exclude
existing rivals from obtaining pool
products from manufacturers.
PoolCorp’s threat was significant. The
loss of sales to PoolCorp could be
‘‘catastrophic’’ to the financial viability
of even major manufacturers. No other
distributor could replace the large
volume of potential lost sales to
PoolCorp, particularly in markets where
PoolCorp is the only distributor. New
entrants could not offer any economic
incentive to manufacturers that would
offset the risks imposed by PoolCorp’s
threats.
VerDate Mar<15>2010
15:34 Nov 25, 2011
Jkt 226001
After receiving these threats,
manufacturers, including the three
‘‘must-have’’ manufacturers, refused to
sell pool products to the new
distributors and canceled any preexisting orders. PoolCorp thus
effectively foreclosed new distributors
from obtaining pool products from
manufacturers that represented more
than 70 percent of all pool product
sales.
In some cases, the new distributors
were able to purchase pool products
from other distributors. This
counterstrategy, however, did not
mitigate the effects of PoolCorp’s
conduct. As a general rule, distributors
do not sell pool products to other
distributors. Even when possible, this
alternative is not a viable long-term
strategy because it substantially
increases the entrant’s costs and lessens
its quality of service. For example,
buying pool products from a distributor
forces the new distributor entrant to pay
transportation costs from the
distributor’s location rather than
receiving free shipping under
manufacturer programs. The purchases
are also at a marked-up price and do not
qualify for key manufacturer year-end
rebates.
By effectively increasing its rivals’
costs, PoolCorp’s exclusionary policy
prevented the new distributor entrants
from being able to compete aggressively
on price. Additionally, without full
control of their inventory, the entrants’
ability to provide quality service to their
dealer customers was diminished.
PoolCorp specifically targeted new
entrants, rather than established rivals,
because the new distributors
represented a significant competitive
threat due to their likelihood to compete
aggressively on price in order to earn
new business. PoolCorp’s conduct,
therefore, had the purpose and effect of
maintaining and enhancing PoolCorp’s
monopoly power in numerous local
markets where its dominance would
otherwise be threatened by new
entrants. PoolCorp’s exclusionary
policy, therefore, has likely resulted in
higher prices and reduced output. There
are no procompetitive efficiencies that
justify PoolCorp’s conduct.
II. Legal Analysis
The offense of monopolization under
§ 2 of the Sherman Act has two
elements: (1) the possession of
monopoly power in the relevant market;
and (2) the willful acquisition,
enhancement or maintenance of that
PO 00000
Frm 00029
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
72925
power through exclusionary conduct.2
A monopolist’s refusal to deal with a
firm if that firm also deals with a rival
has long been recognized as
exclusionary conduct. Exclusionary
practices violate Section 2 of the
Sherman Act when the challenged
conduct significantly impairs the ability
of rivals to compete effectively with the
respondent and thus to constrain its
exercise of monopoly power.3
The factual allegations in the
complaint regarding market structure
support a finding of monopoly power
and competitive harm. PoolCorp’s ‘‘all
or nothing’’ threats acted as a powerful
deterrent to manufacturers against
dealing with new distributor entrants by
jeopardizing a large and irreplaceable
percentage of the manufacturer’s sales.
PoolCorp’s conduct effectively
foreclosed new entrants from
manufacturers representing more than
70 percent of pool product sales. New
entrants were unable to provide any
economic incentive to manufacturers
that could offset the risk posed by
PoolCorp’s threats. Raising rivals’ costs
by restraining their supply of inputs can
be a ‘‘particularly effective method of
anticompetitive exclusion.’’ 4
Additionally, the work-around
strategy employed by some new entrants
of purchasing pool products from other
distributors significantly raised their
costs and reduced their ability to
provide quality service. PoolCorp’s
exclusionary policy therefore prevented
these firms from providing a meaningful
2 Verizon Commun’s. v. Law Offices of Curtis V.
Trinko LLP., 540 U.S. 398, 407 (2004); United States
v. Grinnell Corp., 384 U.S. 563, 570–71 (1966).
3 E.g., Aspen Skiing Co. v. Aspen Highlands
Skiing Corp., 472 U.S. 585, 605 & n. 32 (1985)
(exclusionary conduct ‘‘tends to impair the
opportunities of rivals’’ but ‘‘either does not further
competition on the merits or does so in an
unnecessarily restrictive way’’) (citations omitted);
see also Lorain Journal Co. v. United States, 342
U.S. 143, 151–54 (1951) (condemning newspaper’s
refusal to deal with customers that also advertised
on rival radio station because it harmed the radio
station’s ability to compete); United States v.
Microsoft, 253 F.3d 34, 68–71 (D.C. Cir. 2001)
(condemning exclusive agreements that prevented
rivals from ‘‘pos[ing] a real threat to Microsoft’s
monopoly’’); United States v. Dentsply, 399 F.3d
181, 191 (3d Cir. 2005) (condemning policy that
kept competitors below ‘‘the critical level necessary
for any rival to pose a real threat to Dentsply’s
market share’’).
4 See Thomas G. Krattenmaker & Steven C. Salop,
Anticompetitive Exclusion: Raising Rivals’ Costs to
Achieve Power Over Price, 96 Yale L.J. 209, 224
(1986) (explaining that this method of exclusion
allows a dominant firm to use its vertical
relationships to create additional horizontal market
power); see also Dentsply, 399 F.3d at 195 (holding
‘‘all or nothing’’ ultimatum exclusionary when it
‘‘created a strong economic incentive for dealers to
reject competing lines in favor of Dentsply’s
teeth.’’); In re Transitions Optical, Inc., 75 FR 10799
(Mar. 2010) (proposed complaint and analysis to aid
public comment).
E:\FR\FM\28NON1.SGM
28NON1
72926
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 228 / Monday, November 28, 2011 / Notices
constraint on PoolCorp’s monopoly
prices.
Notably, PoolCorp’s conduct targeted
new entry and did not exclude existing
rivals. The test for exclusionary
conduct, however, is not total
foreclosure, but ‘‘whether the
challenged practices bar a substantial
number of rivals or severely restrict the
market’s ambit.’’ 5 New entrants may
have a more disruptive impact on the
market than established firms because
they may have an increased incentive to
compete aggressively on price in order
to win business. Conduct that
artificially raises entry barriers by
increasing the scale, cost or time of
entry harms consumers by providing a
greater opportunity for monopoly
pricing.6
A monopolist may rebut a prima facie
showing of competitive harm by
showing that the challenged conduct is
reasonably necessary to achieve a
procompetitive benefit. Any efficiency
benefit, if proven, must be balanced
against the harm caused by the
challenged conduct.
There are no procompetitive
efficiencies that justify PoolCorp’s
conduct. In some cases, for example,
exclusive arrangements with suppliers
could be necessary to prevent freeriding or to secure adequate supply.
Here, however, PoolCorp did not offer
any services upon which a new entrant
could free-ride. Further, the pool
industry is not subject to product
shortfalls that could justify exclusive
arrangements with suppliers. In short,
PoolCorp’s practice of foreclosing new
entrants from supply did not help
PoolCorp compete on the merits by
improving its efficiency, quality or
prices.
III. The Order
pmangrum on DSK3VPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
The proposed Consent Order
remedies PoolCorp’s anticompetitive
conduct. Paragraph II of the Order
addresses the core of PoolCorp’s
conduct. Specifically, Paragraph II of
5 LePage’s, Inc. v. 3M, 324 F.3d 141, 159 (3d Cir.
2003); see also Dentsply, 399 F.3d at 190
(explaining that ‘‘it is not necessary that all
competition be removed from the market’’).
6 Herbert Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law ¶ 1802c, at
64 (2d ed. 2002) (‘‘Consumer injury results from the
delay that the dominant firm imposes on the
smaller rival’s growth’’); see also Microsoft, 253
F.3d at 79 (‘‘it would be inimical to the purpose of
the Sherman Act to allow monopolists free reign to
squash nascent, albeit unproven, competitors at
will’’); LePage’s, 324 F.3d at 159 (‘‘When a
monopolist’s actions are designed to prevent one or
more new or potential competitors from gaining a
foothold in the market by exclusionary, i.e.,
predatory, conduct, its success in that goal is not
only injurious to the potential competitor but also
to competition in general.’’).
VerDate Mar<15>2010
15:34 Nov 25, 2011
Jkt 226001
the proposed Consent Order prohibits
PoolCorp from:
• Conditioning the sale or purchase of
pool products, or membership in
PoolCorp’s preferred vendor programs,
on the intended or actual sale of pool
products by a manufacturer to any
distributor other than PoolCorp;
• Pressuring, urging or otherwise
coercing manufacturers to refrain from
selling, or to limit their sales, to any
distributors other than PoolCorp; and
• Discriminating or retaliating against
a manufacturer for selling, or intending
to sell, pool products to any distributor
other than PoolCorp.
The definition of ‘‘distributor’’
includes any entity that buys pool
products directly from manufacturers
and resells those products to dealers or
others. The Order explicitly allows
PoolCorp to enter into exclusive
agreements with manufacturers to
purchase private-label pool products.
Paragraph III of the Proposed Order
requires PoolCorp to implement an
antitrust compliance program.
Paragraph IV–VI impose reporting and
other compliance requirements. The
Order will expire in 20 years.
By direction of the Commission,
Commissioner Rosch dissenting.
Donald S. Clark,
Secretary.
Statement of Commissioners Julie Brill,
Jon Leibowitz and Edith Ramirez
Regarding the Complaint and Proposed
Consent Order in In Re Pool
Corporation
November 21, 2011
The Commission is today issuing for
public comment a Complaint and Order
that would resolve allegations that Pool
Corporation (‘‘PoolCorp’’) used
anticompetitive acts and practices to
exclude rivals from, and to maintain its
monopoly power in, several local pool
product distribution markets, in
violation of Section 5 of the Federal
Trade Commission Act, 15 U.S.C. 45.
On the basis of staff’s investigation
and as outlined in the Complaint, we
have reason to believe that a violation
of the antitrust laws has occurred—and
that Commission action is in the public
interest. 15 U.S.C. 45(b). Specifically,
the Complaint alleges that PoolCorp,
which possesses monopoly power in
many local distribution markets,
threatened its suppliers (i.e., pool
product manufacturers) that it would no
longer distribute a manufacturer’s
products on a nationwide basis if that
manufacturer sold its products to a new
distributor that was attempting to enter
a local market. Although these
manufacturers preferred to have a broad
PO 00000
Frm 00030
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
and diverse distribution network, they
declined to add distributors because
they feared retribution from PoolCorp.
These decisions were not made for
independent business reasons.7
As alleged in the Complaint,
PoolCorp’s actions foreclosed new
entrants from obtaining pool products
from manufacturers representing more
than 70 percent of sales. Significantly,
there is no efficiency justification for
PoolCorp’s conduct. That is, without
any legitimate justification, PoolCorp
dictated whether new competitors could
access the full range of merchandise
needed to compete effectively in the
market. Cf. Toys ‘‘R’’ Us, Inc. v. FTC,
221 F.3d 928, 930 (7th Cir. 2000)
(actions by dominant toy retailer to
prevent would-be entrants from
obtaining access to toys judged to be
anticompetitive). Some of PoolCorp’s
targets were able to survive by
purchasing pool products from other
distributors rather than directly from the
manufacturers. However, we assess
consumer harm relative to market
conditions that would have existed but
for the respondent’s allegedly unlawful
conduct. Here, PoolCorp’s strategy
significantly increased a new entrant’s
costs of obtaining pool products.
Conduct by a monopolist that raises
rivals’ costs can harm competition by
creating an artificial price floor or
deterring investments in quality, service
and innovation.8 The higher cost
structure PoolCorp imposed on new
entrants prevented them from providing
a competitive constraint to PoolCorp’s
alleged monopoly prices. And without
full control of their inventory, the new
distributors’ ability to provide high
quality service to their dealer customers
was diminished. The harm to
consumers that occurred as a result was
substantial. In the end, consumers had
fewer choices and were forced to pay
higher prices for pool products.
Although we recognize that
PoolCorp’s alleged conduct did not
target incumbent distributors, we
nevertheless have reason to believe that
the conduct harmed competition and
consumers. Separate from PoolCorp,
7 We disagree with Commissioner Rosch’s
conclusion that manufacturers refused to deal with
new entrants for independent business reasons. In
our view, the evidence demonstrates a causal
relationship between the manufacturers’ decisions
and PoolCorp’s alleged conduct.
8 See, e.g., Thomas G. Krattenmaker & Steven C.
Salop, Anticompetitive Exclusion: Raising Rivals’
Costs to Achieve Power Over Price, 96 Yale L.J. 209,
224 (1986) (finding that a dominant firm’s strategy
of restraining rivals’ access to supply can be a
‘‘particularly effective method of anticompetitive
exclusion’’ because it allows the dominant firm to
use its vertical relationships to create additional
horizontal market power).
E:\FR\FM\28NON1.SGM
28NON1
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 228 / Monday, November 28, 2011 / Notices
there are few, if any, incumbent
distributors in the local markets at issue
here. By targeting new distributor
entrants, PoolCorp’s conduct harmed
the very companies that were most
likely to compete aggressively on price
and to introduce innovative services or
ways of doing business.9 The
Commission has seen this pattern
before. The targets of anticompetitive
exclusion are often the new rivals that
incumbents foresee as most likely to
shake up the market and benefit
consumers at the expense of
incumbents.10 We fail to do our job if
we permit a monopolist to decide,
without sufficient efficiency
justification, whether or on what terms
a rival will be permitted to enter the
market.
Because we have reason to believe
that PoolCorp’s conduct had the
purpose and effect of maintaining
PoolCorp’s monopoly power in
numerous local markets where its
dominance was threatened by new
distributor entrants, we support the
attached Complaint and Order.
Dissenting Statement of J. Thomas
Rosch In the Matter of Pool
Corporation, FTC File No. 101–0115
November 21, 2011
This case presents the novel situation
of a company willing to enter into a
consent decree notwithstanding a lack
of evidence indicating that a violation
has occurred. The FTC Act requires that
the Commission find a ‘‘reason to
believe’’ that a violation has occurred
and determine that Commission action
would be in the public interest any time
it issues a complaint. 15 U.S.C. 45(b). In
my view, the same standard applies
regardless of whether the Commission is
seeking a litigated decree or a consent
decree for the charged violation.
Accordingly, I would reject the
proposed consent decree and close the
investigation.
After a year and a half of
investigation, we have not been able to
identify any harm to consumers or
competition as a result of actions by
pmangrum on DSK3VPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
9 See
id. at 246 (explaining that potential
competition by new entrants can provide a
‘‘significant competitive check’’ distinct from
established firms).
10 See, e.g., Allied Tube & Conduit Corp. v. Indian
Head, Inc., 486 U.S. 492, 499–500 (1988)
(condemning association action to prevent
inclusion of plastic conduits in relevant standard);
Realcomp II, LTD. v. FTC, 635 F.3d 815 (6th Cir.
2011) (condemning Multiple Listing Service rules
that disadvantaged new brokerage model), cert.
denied, 2011 U.S. Lexis 7292 (Oct. 11, 2011); Toys
‘‘R’’ Us, Inc. v. FTC, 221 F.3d 928 (7th Cir. 2000)
(condemning dominant toy company’s actions that
limited sources of toys available to new warehouse
clubs).
VerDate Mar<15>2010
15:34 Nov 25, 2011
Jkt 226001
Pool Corporation, Inc. (‘‘PoolCorp’’),
and further investigation appears
unlikely to uncover such effects. As an
initial matter, it is important to note
that, even accepting the allegations in
the complaint, PoolCorp did not engage
in a general pattern of exclusionary
conduct. Rather, the complaint alleges
that PoolCorp threatened manufacturers
not to supply an entering distributor in
various local markets. There is no
allegation that PoolCorp sought to
restrict supply to (1) incumbents in any
of these local markets, (2) established
distributors seeking to expand into
markets dominated by PoolCorp, or (3)
established distributors in any of the
dozens of other local markets across the
country.
The limited scope of PoolCorp’s
alleged exclusionary conduct is, of
course, no defense. PoolCorp’s alleged
threats to manufacturers, had they been
successful, may well have violated the
antitrust laws. But that is not what
happened. The investigation revealed
that PoolCorp’s demands were not
honored by manufacturers. Instead, the
evidence showed that manufacturers
made unilateral decisions not to supply
the de novo entrants in the various local
markets.
There were legitimate reasons for pool
equipment manufacturers not to sell to
these entrants. A manufacturer will
typically accept a new distributor only
if the distributor will add to the value
of the distribution network by, for
example, improving growth
opportunities or increasing promotional
activities. Manufacturers often require a
de novo entrant to have adequate
facilities, a history of successful
operations, and a favorable credit
history before supporting it. In this case,
many of the allegedly excluded de novo
entrants did not satisfy these
requirements. The lack of evidence
establishing causation between
PoolCorp’s requests and action by the
manufacturers, combined with plausible
justifications for the manufacturers’
actions, should be fatal to this case.
Another problem with this case is that
no entrants were actually excluded.11
11 The
majority statement purports to be based on
the Complaint. However, the majority statement
ignores the central theory of the Complaint—
exclusion of rivals through foreclosure of supply
(Complaint ¶¶ 18–28)—and does not assert that any
rivals were actually excluded. Instead, the majority
statement focuses on an alternative theory of
competitive harm—raising rivals’ costs—on which
the Complaint offers scant details. (Complaint ¶¶
29–31.) As support for this theory, the majority
statement relies on an article by Krattenmaker and
Salop. See Thomas G. Krattenmaker & Steven C.
Salop, Anticompetitive Exclusion: Raising Rivals’
Costs to Achieve Power Over Price, 96 Yale L.J. 209,
224 (1986). As these authors note, however, a
raising rivals’ costs strategy is unlikely to be
PO 00000
Frm 00031
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
72927
That is because the entrants were able
to obtain supplies from other
manufacturers or distributors. The only
claim to the contrary is in Paragraph 28
of the complaint, which alleges that in
Baton Rouge, ‘‘the new entrant’s
business ultimately failed in 2005’’
because of the lack of ‘‘direct access to
the manufacturers’ pool products.’’ The
complaint neglects to mention that this
entrant was able to secure supplies from
other sources and later sold itself to an
established out-of-state distributor.
Since then, that distributor, which has
had full access to supplies, has been a
highly effective rival to PoolCorp. Thus,
to the extent PoolCorp’s threats had an
effect in Baton Rouge, they may have
led to more, not less, competition.
A third problem with this case is that
there was no consumer injury. The
investigation did not uncover price
increases, service degradation, or other
anticompetitive effects in any local
markets.12 Economic analysis
corroborated these results and suggested
that even if PoolCorp had completely
foreclosed its rivals, the pricing effects
would have been minimal. The lack of
consumer harm should not be surprising
given that PoolCorp’s actions, at most,
raised the costs of a single competitor in
each local market, without affecting
other incumbents or the entry prospects
of established, out-of-market dealers.
The lack of consumer injury is also
corroborated by the very low entry
barriers in this industry. Opening a pool
supply distributorship requires access to
one or more of the major equipment
suppliers, a few trucks, a medium-sized
warehouse, access to credit, and no
more than ten employees. There are
hundreds of profitable pool supply
distributors, and entry and expansion
are frequent events. Thus, any effort to
exclude a competitor would become a
game of whack-a-mole: As soon as one
competitor is driven from the market,
another would pop up.
Accordingly, I cannot find that there
is a ‘‘reason to believe’’ that a violation
occurred or that accepting the proposed
consent decree would be in the public
successful in a market with low entry barriers. Id.
at 225 (entry must ‘‘be difficult’’), 236 n.85
(‘‘Obviously, some barriers to entry and expansion
must exist for price to rise.’’). Here, neither the
complaint nor the majority statement alleges that
there are any significant barriers to entry in this
industry.
12 The basis for the majority statement’s claim
that there was ‘‘substantial’’ consumer harm
resulting from the alleged conduct of Respondent is
a mystery. The complaint contains no factual
allegations of any harm to consumers, much less
‘‘substantial’’ harm. Likewise, there are no factual
allegations in the complaint corroborating the
majority’s claim that consumers ‘‘had fewer choices
and were forced to pay higher prices for pool
products.’’
E:\FR\FM\28NON1.SGM
28NON1
72928
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 228 / Monday, November 28, 2011 / Notices
interest. 15 U.S.C. 45(b). Furthermore, I
question whether this investigation
represented a wise use of Commission
resources, particularly given the austere
climate in which we are operating. Even
accepting all of the allegations in the
complaint as true, the likely consumer
injury would have amounted to just a
few thousand dollars.
[FR Doc. 2011–30435 Filed 11–25–11; 8:45 am]
National Institute for
Occupational Safety and Health
(NIOSH), Department of Health and
Human Services (HHS).
AGENCY:
HHS gives notice concerning
the final effect of the HHS decision to
designate a class of employees from
Vitro Manufacturing in Canonsburg,
Pennsylvania, as an addition to the
Special Exposure Cohort (SEC) under
the Energy Employees Occupational
Illness Compensation Program Act of
2000. On October 18, 2011, as provided
for under 42 U.S.C. 7384q(b), the
Secretary of HHS designated the
following class of employees as an
addition to the SEC:
SUMMARY:
All Atomic Weapons Employees who
worked at Vitro Manufacturing in
Canonsburg, Pennsylvania, from January 1,
1960 through September 30, 1965, for a
number of work days aggregating at least 250
work days, occurring either solely under this
employment or in combination with work
days within the parameters established for
one or more other classes of employees in the
Special Exposure Cohort.
This designation became effective on
November 17, 2011, as provided for
under 42 U.S.C. 7384l(14)(C). Hence,
beginning on November 17, 2011,
members of this class of employees,
defined as reported in this notice,
became members of the Special
Exposure Cohort.
pmangrum on DSK3VPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
[FR Doc. 2011–30586 Filed 11–25–11; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 4163–19–P
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
Stuart L. Hinnefeld, Director, Division
of Compensation Analysis and Support,
National Institute for Occupational
Safety and Health (NIOSH), 4676
Columbia Parkway, MS C–46,
Cincinnati, OH 45226, Telephone (877)
222–7570. Information requests can also
National Institute for
Occupational Safety and Health
(NIOSH), Department of Health and
Human Services (HHS).
AGENCY:
National Institute for
Occupational Safety and Health
(NIOSH), Department of Health and
Human Services (HHS).
ACTION: Notice.
HHS gives notice concerning
the final effect of the HHS decision to
designate a class of employees from
W.R. Grace and Company in Curtis Bay,
Maryland, as an addition to the Special
Exposure Cohort (SEC) under the Energy
Employees Occupational Illness
Compensation Program Act of 2000. On
October 18, 2011, as provided for under
42 U.S.C. 7384q(b), the Secretary of
HHS designated the following class of
employees as an addition to the SEC:
SUMMARY:
Notice.
Jkt 226001
Final Effect of Designation of a Class
of Employees for Addition to the
Special Exposure Cohort
AGENCY:
Final Effect of Designation of a Class
of Employees for Addition to the
Special Exposure Cohort
15:34 Nov 25, 2011
John Howard,
Director, National Institute for Occupational
Safety and Health.
Final Effect of Designation of a Class
of Employees for Addition to the
Special Exposure Cohort
DEPARTMENT OF HEALTH AND
HUMAN SERVICES
VerDate Mar<15>2010
DEPARTMENT OF HEALTH AND
HUMAN SERVICES
DEPARTMENT OF HEALTH AND
HUMAN SERVICES
BILLING CODE 6750–01–P
ACTION:
be submitted by email to
DCAS@CDC.GOV.
All Atomic Weapons Employees who
worked at any building or area at the facility
owned by W.R. Grace and Company in Curtis
Bay, Maryland, for the operational period
from May 1, 1956 through January 31, 1958,
for a number of work days aggregating at least
250 work days, occurring either solely under
this employment or in combination with
work days within the parameters established
for one or more other classes of employees
included in the Special Exposure Cohort.
This designation became effective on
November 17, 2011, as provided for
under 42 U.S.C. 7384l(14)(C). Hence,
beginning on November 17, 2011,
members of this class of employees,
defined as reported in this notice,
became members of the Special
Exposure Cohort.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
Stuart L. Hinnefeld, Director, Division
of Compensation Analysis and Support,
National Institute for Occupational
Safety and Health (NIOSH), 4676
Columbia Parkway, MS C–46,
Cincinnati, OH 45226, Telephone (877)
222–7570. Information requests can also
be submitted by email to
DCAS@CDC.GOV.
John Howard,
Director, National Institute for Occupational
Safety and Health.
ACTION:
Notice.
HHS gives notice concerning
the final effect of the HHS decision to
designate a class of employees from the
Y–12 facility in Oak Ridge, Tennessee,
as an addition to the Special Exposure
Cohort (SEC) under the Energy
Employees Occupational Illness
Compensation Program Act of 2000. On
October 18, 2011, as provided for under
42 U.S.C. 7384q(b), the Secretary of
HHS designated the following class of
employees as an addition to the SEC:
SUMMARY:
All employees of the Department of
Energy, its predecessor agencies, and their
contractors and subcontractors who worked
at the Y–12 facility in Oak Ridge, Tennessee,
during the period from January 1, 1948
through December 31, 1957, for a number of
work days aggregating at least 250 work days,
occurring either solely under this
employment or in combination with work
days within the parameters established for
one or more other classes of employees in the
Special Exposure Cohort.
This designation became effective on
November 17, 2011, as provided for
under 42 U.S.C. 7384l(14)(C). Hence,
beginning on November 17, 2011,
members of this class of employees,
defined as reported in this notice,
became members of the Special
Exposure Cohort.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
Stuart L. Hinnefeld, Director, Division
of Compensation Analysis and Support,
National Institute for Occupational
Safety and Health (NIOSH), 4676
Columbia Parkway, MS C–46,
Cincinnati, OH 45226, Telephone (877)
222–7570. Information requests can also
be submitted by email to
DCAS@CDC.GOV.
John Howard,
Director, National Institute for Occupational
Safety and Health.
[FR Doc. 2011–30589 Filed 11–25–11; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 4163–19–P
[FR Doc. 2011–30593 Filed 11–25–11; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 4163–19–P
PO 00000
Frm 00032
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 9990
E:\FR\FM\28NON1.SGM
28NON1
Agencies
[Federal Register Volume 76, Number 228 (Monday, November 28, 2011)]
[Notices]
[Pages 72923-72928]
From the Federal Register Online via the Government Printing Office [www.gpo.gov]
[FR Doc No: 2011-30435]
=======================================================================
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION
[File No. 101 0115]
Pool Corporation; Analysis To Aid Public Comment
AGENCY: Federal Trade Commission.
ACTION: Proposed consent agreement.
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
SUMMARY: The consent agreement in this matter settles alleged
violations of federal law prohibiting unfair or deceptive acts or
practices or unfair methods of competition. The attached Analysis to
Aid Public Comment describes both the allegations in the draft
complaint and the terms of the consent order--embodied in the consent
agreement--that would settle these allegations.
DATES: Comments must be received on or before December 22, 2011.
ADDRESSES: Interested parties may file a comment online or on paper, by
following the instructions in the Request for Comment part of the
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION section below. Write ``PoolCorp, File No. 101
0115'' on your comment, and file your comment online at https://ftcpublic.commentworks.com/ftc/poolcorpconsent, by following the
instructions on the Web-based form. If you prefer to file your comment
on paper, mail or deliver your comment to the following address:
Federal Trade Commission, Office of the Secretary, Room H-113 (Annex
D), 600 Pennsylvania Avenue NW., Washington, DC 20580.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: Linda Holleran (202) 326-2267, FTC,
Bureau of Competition, 600 Pennsylvania Avenue NW., Washington, DC
20580.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: Pursuant to section 6(f) of the Federal
Trade Commission Act, 38 Stat. 721, 15 U.S.C. 46(f), and Sec. 2.34 of
the Commission's Rules of Practice, 16 CFR 2.34, notice is hereby given
that the above-captioned consent agreement containing a consent order
to cease and desist, having been filed with and accepted, subject to
final approval, by the Commission, has been placed on the public record
for a period of thirty (30) days. The following Analysis to Aid Public
Comment describes the terms of the consent agreement, and the
allegations in the complaint. An electronic copy of the full text of
the consent agreement package can be obtained from the FTC Home Page
(for November 21, 2011), on the World Wide Web, at https://www.ftc.gov/os/actions.shtm. A paper copy can be obtained from the FTC Public
Reference Room, Room 130-H, 600 Pennsylvania Avenue NW., Washington, DC
20580, either in person or by calling (202) 326-2222.
You can file a comment online or on paper. For the Commission to
consider your comment, we must receive it on or before December 22,
2011. Write ``PoolCorp, File No. 101 0115'' on your comment. Your
comment--including your name and your state--will be placed on the
public record of this proceeding, including, to the extent practicable,
on the public Commission Web site, at https://www.ftc.gov/os/publiccomments.shtm. As a matter of discretion, the Commission tries to
remove individuals' home contact information from comments before
placing them on the Commission Web site.
Because your comment will be made public, you are solely
responsible for making sure that your comment does not include any
sensitive personal information, like anyone's Social Security number,
date of birth, driver's license number or other state identification
number or foreign country equivalent, passport number, financial
account number, or credit or debit card number. You are also solely
responsible for making sure that your comment does not include any
sensitive health information, like medical records or other
individually identifiable health information. In addition, do not
include any ``[t]rade secret or any commercial or financial information
which is obtained from any person and which is privileged or
confidential,'' as provided in Section
[[Page 72924]]
6(f) of the FTC Act, 15 U.S.C. 46(f), and FTC Rule 4.10(a)(2), 16 CFR
4.10(a)(2). In particular, do not include competitively sensitive
information such as costs, sales statistics, inventories, formulas,
patterns, devices, manufacturing processes, or customer names.
If you want the Commission to give your comment confidential
treatment, you must file it in paper form, with a request for
confidential treatment, and you have to follow the procedure explained
in FTC Rule 4.9(c), 16 CFR 4.9(c).\1\ Your comment will be kept
confidential only if the FTC General Counsel, in his or her sole
discretion, grants your request in accordance with the law and the
public interest.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1\ In particular, the written request for confidential
treatment that accompanies the comment must include the factual and
legal basis for the request, and must identify the specific portions
of the comment to be withheld from the public record. See FTC Rule
4.9(c), 16 CFR 4.9(c).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Postal mail addressed to the Commission is subject to delay due to
heightened security screening. As a result, we encourage you to submit
your comments online. To make sure that the Commission considers your
online comment, you must file it at https://ftcpublic.commentworks.com/ftc/poolcorpconsent by following the instructions on the web-based
form. If this Notice appears at https://www.regulations.gov/#!home, you
also may file a comment through that Web site.
If you file your comment on paper, write ``PoolCorp, File No. 101
0115'' on your comment and on the envelope, and mail or deliver it to
the following address: Federal Trade Commission, Office of the
Secretary, Room H-113 (Annex D), 600 Pennsylvania Avenue NW.,
Washington, DC 20580. If possible, submit your paper comment to the
Commission by courier or overnight service.
Visit the Commission Web site at https://www.ftc.gov to read this
Notice and the news release describing it. The FTC Act and other laws
that the Commission administers permit the collection of public
comments to consider and use in this proceeding as appropriate. The
Commission will consider all timely and responsive public comments that
it receives on or before December 22, 2011. You can find more
information, including routine uses permitted by the Privacy Act, in
the Commission's privacy policy, at https://www.ftc.gov/ftc/privacy.htm.
Analysis of Agreement Containing Consent Order To Aid Public Comment
The Federal Trade Commission has accepted for public comment an
Agreement Containing Consent Order to Cease and Desist (``Agreement'')
with Pool Corporation (``PoolCorp''). PoolCorp is the world's largest
distributor of products used in the construction, renovation, repair,
service, and maintenance of residential and commercial swimming pools.
The Agreement resolves charges that PoolCorp used exclusionary acts and
practices to maintain its monopoly power in the pool product
distribution market in violation of Section 5 of the Federal Trade
Commission Act, 15 U.S.C. 45.
The administrative complaint that accompanies the Agreement
(``Complaint'') alleges that PoolCorp used its monopoly power in local
geographic markets to prevent manufacturers from supplying pool
products to new entrants since at least 2003. As a result, PoolCorp
foreclosed rival distributors from obtaining pool products--a necessary
input to compete--and significantly raised its rivals' costs, thereby
lowering output, increasing prices, and diminishing consumer choice.
The Commission anticipates that the competitive issues described in
the Complaint will be resolved by accepting the proposed Order, subject
to final approval, contained in the Agreement. The Agreement has been
placed on the public record for 30 days for receipt of comments from
interested members of the public. Comments received during this period
will become part of the public record. After 30 days, the Commission
will again review the Agreement and comments received, and will decide
whether it should withdraw from the Agreement or make final the Order
contained in the Agreement.
The purpose of this Analysis to Aid Public Comment is to invite and
facilitate public comment concerning the proposed Order. It is not
intended to constitute an official interpretation of the Agreement and
proposed Order or in any way to modify their terms.
The Agreement is for settlement purposes only and does not
constitute an admission by PoolCorp that the law has been violated as
alleged in the Complaint or that the facts alleged in the Complaint,
other than jurisdictional facts, are true.
I. The Complaint
The Complaint makes the following allegations.
A. Industry Background
This case involves wholesale distribution in the swimming pool
industry. There are over nine million residential pools in the United
States, and over 250,000 commercial pools operated by hotels, country
clubs, apartment buildings, municipalities, and others. In 2010, the
distribution of pool products was an estimated $3 billion industry in
the United States. Manufacturers use distributors to sell the products
used to build, repair, service, and maintain residential and commercial
swimming pools (``pool products''). Pool products include, among
others, pumps, filters, heaters, covers, cleaners, diving boards,
steps, rails, pool liners, pool walls, and the parts necessary to
maintain pool equipment. Distributors purchase pool products from
manufacturers, warehouse them, and then resell the products to pool
retail stores, pool service companies and pool builders (collectively,
``pool dealers'' or ``dealers''). Dealers, in turn, sell the pool
products to the ultimate consumer: owners of residential and commercial
swimming pools. The swimming pool industry is very fragmented and
wholesale distributors make it more efficient for manufacturers and
dealers to sell their products. Distributors purchase most, if not all,
brands of pool products that are produced by manufacturers so that they
can provide convenient one-stop shopping for their dealer customers.
Distributors also extend credit and provide quick delivery of pool
products to thousands of dealers. The vast majority of dealers are mom-
and-pop operations that are too small to buy directly from
manufacturers; for these dealers, distributors are their only source of
pool products. Distributors also allow manufacturers to operate their
factories year-round by purchasing large quantities of pool products
throughout the year, even though the pool industry is seasonal.
In general, manufacturers are willing to sell their products to any
credit-worthy distributor that has a physical warehouse and personnel
with knowledge of the pool industry. Manufacturers typically prefer to
have two or more distributors selling their products in a local
geographic market in order to ensure that the distributors compete and
give competitive service and prices to their dealer customers.
To compete effectively as a distributor, a firm must be able to buy
pool products directly from manufacturers. There are no cost-effective
alternatives. While there are
[[Page 72925]]
over 100 manufacturers of pool products, there are only three full-line
manufacturers that produce almost all of the products used to operate
or repair swimming pools: Pentair Water Pool & Spa; Zodiac Pool
Systems, Inc.; and Hayward Pool Products. Collectively, these
manufacturers represent more than 50 percent of all pool product sales.
To be successful, a distributor must sell the products of at least one
of these manufacturers. As recognized by PoolCorp, a positive
relationship with these and other manufacturers is ``critical'' to the
success of a distributor.
B. PoolCorp's Monopoly Power
The relevant market is no broader than the wholesale distribution
of pool products in the United States and numerous local geographic
markets. With the exception of large national retail chains that
purchase pool products for their retail centers located throughout the
United States, competition among distributors for sales to dealers
occurs locally. PoolCorp has monopoly power in numerous local markets,
as evidenced by a persistently high market share of 80 percent or more
for the past five years. PoolCorp's conduct of foreclosing new
distributor entrants from obtaining pool products directly from
manufacturers represents a significant barrier to entry.
C. PoolCorp's Conduct
Beginning in 2003 and continuing to today, PoolCorp has implemented
an exclusionary policy that effectively impeded entry by new
distributors by preventing them from being able to purchase pool
products directly from manufacturers. Specifically, when a new
distributor attempted to enter a local geographic market, PoolCorp
threatened manufacturers that it would not deal with them if they also
supplied the new entrant. PoolCorp threatened to terminate the purchase
and sale of the manufacturer's pool products for all 200+ PoolCorp
distribution centers located throughout the United States. PoolCorp's
policy did not exclude existing rivals from obtaining pool products
from manufacturers.
PoolCorp's threat was significant. The loss of sales to PoolCorp
could be ``catastrophic'' to the financial viability of even major
manufacturers. No other distributor could replace the large volume of
potential lost sales to PoolCorp, particularly in markets where
PoolCorp is the only distributor. New entrants could not offer any
economic incentive to manufacturers that would offset the risks imposed
by PoolCorp's threats.
After receiving these threats, manufacturers, including the three
``must-have'' manufacturers, refused to sell pool products to the new
distributors and canceled any pre-existing orders. PoolCorp thus
effectively foreclosed new distributors from obtaining pool products
from manufacturers that represented more than 70 percent of all pool
product sales.
In some cases, the new distributors were able to purchase pool
products from other distributors. This counterstrategy, however, did
not mitigate the effects of PoolCorp's conduct. As a general rule,
distributors do not sell pool products to other distributors. Even when
possible, this alternative is not a viable long-term strategy because
it substantially increases the entrant's costs and lessens its quality
of service. For example, buying pool products from a distributor forces
the new distributor entrant to pay transportation costs from the
distributor's location rather than receiving free shipping under
manufacturer programs. The purchases are also at a marked-up price and
do not qualify for key manufacturer year-end rebates.
By effectively increasing its rivals' costs, PoolCorp's
exclusionary policy prevented the new distributor entrants from being
able to compete aggressively on price. Additionally, without full
control of their inventory, the entrants' ability to provide quality
service to their dealer customers was diminished. PoolCorp specifically
targeted new entrants, rather than established rivals, because the new
distributors represented a significant competitive threat due to their
likelihood to compete aggressively on price in order to earn new
business. PoolCorp's conduct, therefore, had the purpose and effect of
maintaining and enhancing PoolCorp's monopoly power in numerous local
markets where its dominance would otherwise be threatened by new
entrants. PoolCorp's exclusionary policy, therefore, has likely
resulted in higher prices and reduced output. There are no
procompetitive efficiencies that justify PoolCorp's conduct.
II. Legal Analysis
The offense of monopolization under Sec. 2 of the Sherman Act has
two elements: (1) the possession of monopoly power in the relevant
market; and (2) the willful acquisition, enhancement or maintenance of
that power through exclusionary conduct.\2\ A monopolist's refusal to
deal with a firm if that firm also deals with a rival has long been
recognized as exclusionary conduct. Exclusionary practices violate
Section 2 of the Sherman Act when the challenged conduct significantly
impairs the ability of rivals to compete effectively with the
respondent and thus to constrain its exercise of monopoly power.\3\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\2\ Verizon Commun's. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko LLP.,
540 U.S. 398, 407 (2004); United States v. Grinnell Corp., 384 U.S.
563, 570-71 (1966).
\3\ E.g., Aspen Skiing Co. v. Aspen Highlands Skiing Corp., 472
U.S. 585, 605 & n. 32 (1985) (exclusionary conduct ``tends to impair
the opportunities of rivals'' but ``either does not further
competition on the merits or does so in an unnecessarily restrictive
way'') (citations omitted); see also Lorain Journal Co. v. United
States, 342 U.S. 143, 151-54 (1951) (condemning newspaper's refusal
to deal with customers that also advertised on rival radio station
because it harmed the radio station's ability to compete); United
States v. Microsoft, 253 F.3d 34, 68-71 (D.C. Cir. 2001) (condemning
exclusive agreements that prevented rivals from ``pos[ing] a real
threat to Microsoft's monopoly''); United States v. Dentsply, 399
F.3d 181, 191 (3d Cir. 2005) (condemning policy that kept
competitors below ``the critical level necessary for any rival to
pose a real threat to Dentsply's market share'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The factual allegations in the complaint regarding market structure
support a finding of monopoly power and competitive harm. PoolCorp's
``all or nothing'' threats acted as a powerful deterrent to
manufacturers against dealing with new distributor entrants by
jeopardizing a large and irreplaceable percentage of the manufacturer's
sales. PoolCorp's conduct effectively foreclosed new entrants from
manufacturers representing more than 70 percent of pool product sales.
New entrants were unable to provide any economic incentive to
manufacturers that could offset the risk posed by PoolCorp's threats.
Raising rivals' costs by restraining their supply of inputs can be a
``particularly effective method of anticompetitive exclusion.'' \4\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\4\ See Thomas G. Krattenmaker & Steven C. Salop,
Anticompetitive Exclusion: Raising Rivals' Costs to Achieve Power
Over Price, 96 Yale L.J. 209, 224 (1986) (explaining that this
method of exclusion allows a dominant firm to use its vertical
relationships to create additional horizontal market power); see
also Dentsply, 399 F.3d at 195 (holding ``all or nothing'' ultimatum
exclusionary when it ``created a strong economic incentive for
dealers to reject competing lines in favor of Dentsply's teeth.'');
In re Transitions Optical, Inc., 75 FR 10799 (Mar. 2010) (proposed
complaint and analysis to aid public comment).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Additionally, the work-around strategy employed by some new
entrants of purchasing pool products from other distributors
significantly raised their costs and reduced their ability to provide
quality service. PoolCorp's exclusionary policy therefore prevented
these firms from providing a meaningful
[[Page 72926]]
constraint on PoolCorp's monopoly prices.
Notably, PoolCorp's conduct targeted new entry and did not exclude
existing rivals. The test for exclusionary conduct, however, is not
total foreclosure, but ``whether the challenged practices bar a
substantial number of rivals or severely restrict the market's ambit.''
\5\ New entrants may have a more disruptive impact on the market than
established firms because they may have an increased incentive to
compete aggressively on price in order to win business. Conduct that
artificially raises entry barriers by increasing the scale, cost or
time of entry harms consumers by providing a greater opportunity for
monopoly pricing.\6\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\5\ LePage's, Inc. v. 3M, 324 F.3d 141, 159 (3d Cir. 2003); see
also Dentsply, 399 F.3d at 190 (explaining that ``it is not
necessary that all competition be removed from the market'').
\6\ Herbert Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law ] 1802c, at 64 (2d ed.
2002) (``Consumer injury results from the delay that the dominant
firm imposes on the smaller rival's growth''); see also Microsoft,
253 F.3d at 79 (``it would be inimical to the purpose of the Sherman
Act to allow monopolists free reign to squash nascent, albeit
unproven, competitors at will''); LePage's, 324 F.3d at 159 (``When
a monopolist's actions are designed to prevent one or more new or
potential competitors from gaining a foothold in the market by
exclusionary, i.e., predatory, conduct, its success in that goal is
not only injurious to the potential competitor but also to
competition in general.'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
A monopolist may rebut a prima facie showing of competitive harm by
showing that the challenged conduct is reasonably necessary to achieve
a procompetitive benefit. Any efficiency benefit, if proven, must be
balanced against the harm caused by the challenged conduct.
There are no procompetitive efficiencies that justify PoolCorp's
conduct. In some cases, for example, exclusive arrangements with
suppliers could be necessary to prevent free-riding or to secure
adequate supply. Here, however, PoolCorp did not offer any services
upon which a new entrant could free-ride. Further, the pool industry is
not subject to product shortfalls that could justify exclusive
arrangements with suppliers. In short, PoolCorp's practice of
foreclosing new entrants from supply did not help PoolCorp compete on
the merits by improving its efficiency, quality or prices.
III. The Order
The proposed Consent Order remedies PoolCorp's anticompetitive
conduct. Paragraph II of the Order addresses the core of PoolCorp's
conduct. Specifically, Paragraph II of the proposed Consent Order
prohibits PoolCorp from:
Conditioning the sale or purchase of pool products, or
membership in PoolCorp's preferred vendor programs, on the intended or
actual sale of pool products by a manufacturer to any distributor other
than PoolCorp;
Pressuring, urging or otherwise coercing manufacturers to
refrain from selling, or to limit their sales, to any distributors
other than PoolCorp; and
Discriminating or retaliating against a manufacturer for
selling, or intending to sell, pool products to any distributor other
than PoolCorp.
The definition of ``distributor'' includes any entity that buys
pool products directly from manufacturers and resells those products to
dealers or others. The Order explicitly allows PoolCorp to enter into
exclusive agreements with manufacturers to purchase private-label pool
products.
Paragraph III of the Proposed Order requires PoolCorp to implement
an antitrust compliance program. Paragraph IV-VI impose reporting and
other compliance requirements. The Order will expire in 20 years.
By direction of the Commission, Commissioner Rosch dissenting.
Donald S. Clark,
Secretary.
Statement of Commissioners Julie Brill, Jon Leibowitz and Edith Ramirez
Regarding the Complaint and Proposed Consent Order in In Re Pool
Corporation
November 21, 2011
The Commission is today issuing for public comment a Complaint and
Order that would resolve allegations that Pool Corporation
(``PoolCorp'') used anticompetitive acts and practices to exclude
rivals from, and to maintain its monopoly power in, several local pool
product distribution markets, in violation of Section 5 of the Federal
Trade Commission Act, 15 U.S.C. 45.
On the basis of staff's investigation and as outlined in the
Complaint, we have reason to believe that a violation of the antitrust
laws has occurred--and that Commission action is in the public
interest. 15 U.S.C. 45(b). Specifically, the Complaint alleges that
PoolCorp, which possesses monopoly power in many local distribution
markets, threatened its suppliers (i.e., pool product manufacturers)
that it would no longer distribute a manufacturer's products on a
nationwide basis if that manufacturer sold its products to a new
distributor that was attempting to enter a local market. Although these
manufacturers preferred to have a broad and diverse distribution
network, they declined to add distributors because they feared
retribution from PoolCorp. These decisions were not made for
independent business reasons.\7\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\7\ We disagree with Commissioner Rosch's conclusion that
manufacturers refused to deal with new entrants for independent
business reasons. In our view, the evidence demonstrates a causal
relationship between the manufacturers' decisions and PoolCorp's
alleged conduct.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
As alleged in the Complaint, PoolCorp's actions foreclosed new
entrants from obtaining pool products from manufacturers representing
more than 70 percent of sales. Significantly, there is no efficiency
justification for PoolCorp's conduct. That is, without any legitimate
justification, PoolCorp dictated whether new competitors could access
the full range of merchandise needed to compete effectively in the
market. Cf. Toys ``R'' Us, Inc. v. FTC, 221 F.3d 928, 930 (7th Cir.
2000) (actions by dominant toy retailer to prevent would-be entrants
from obtaining access to toys judged to be anticompetitive). Some of
PoolCorp's targets were able to survive by purchasing pool products
from other distributors rather than directly from the manufacturers.
However, we assess consumer harm relative to market conditions that
would have existed but for the respondent's allegedly unlawful conduct.
Here, PoolCorp's strategy significantly increased a new entrant's costs
of obtaining pool products. Conduct by a monopolist that raises rivals'
costs can harm competition by creating an artificial price floor or
deterring investments in quality, service and innovation.\8\ The higher
cost structure PoolCorp imposed on new entrants prevented them from
providing a competitive constraint to PoolCorp's alleged monopoly
prices. And without full control of their inventory, the new
distributors' ability to provide high quality service to their dealer
customers was diminished. The harm to consumers that occurred as a
result was substantial. In the end, consumers had fewer choices and
were forced to pay higher prices for pool products.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\8\ See, e.g., Thomas G. Krattenmaker & Steven C. Salop,
Anticompetitive Exclusion: Raising Rivals' Costs to Achieve Power
Over Price, 96 Yale L.J. 209, 224 (1986) (finding that a dominant
firm's strategy of restraining rivals' access to supply can be a
``particularly effective method of anticompetitive exclusion''
because it allows the dominant firm to use its vertical
relationships to create additional horizontal market power).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Although we recognize that PoolCorp's alleged conduct did not
target incumbent distributors, we nevertheless have reason to believe
that the conduct harmed competition and consumers. Separate from
PoolCorp,
[[Page 72927]]
there are few, if any, incumbent distributors in the local markets at
issue here. By targeting new distributor entrants, PoolCorp's conduct
harmed the very companies that were most likely to compete aggressively
on price and to introduce innovative services or ways of doing
business.\9\ The Commission has seen this pattern before. The targets
of anticompetitive exclusion are often the new rivals that incumbents
foresee as most likely to shake up the market and benefit consumers at
the expense of incumbents.\10\ We fail to do our job if we permit a
monopolist to decide, without sufficient efficiency justification,
whether or on what terms a rival will be permitted to enter the market.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\9\ See id. at 246 (explaining that potential competition by new
entrants can provide a ``significant competitive check'' distinct
from established firms).
\10\ See, e.g., Allied Tube & Conduit Corp. v. Indian Head,
Inc., 486 U.S. 492, 499-500 (1988) (condemning association action to
prevent inclusion of plastic conduits in relevant standard);
Realcomp II, LTD. v. FTC, 635 F.3d 815 (6th Cir. 2011) (condemning
Multiple Listing Service rules that disadvantaged new brokerage
model), cert. denied, 2011 U.S. Lexis 7292 (Oct. 11, 2011); Toys
``R'' Us, Inc. v. FTC, 221 F.3d 928 (7th Cir. 2000) (condemning
dominant toy company's actions that limited sources of toys
available to new warehouse clubs).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Because we have reason to believe that PoolCorp's conduct had the
purpose and effect of maintaining PoolCorp's monopoly power in numerous
local markets where its dominance was threatened by new distributor
entrants, we support the attached Complaint and Order.
Dissenting Statement of J. Thomas Rosch In the Matter of Pool
Corporation, FTC File No. 101-0115
November 21, 2011
This case presents the novel situation of a company willing to
enter into a consent decree notwithstanding a lack of evidence
indicating that a violation has occurred. The FTC Act requires that the
Commission find a ``reason to believe'' that a violation has occurred
and determine that Commission action would be in the public interest
any time it issues a complaint. 15 U.S.C. 45(b). In my view, the same
standard applies regardless of whether the Commission is seeking a
litigated decree or a consent decree for the charged violation.
Accordingly, I would reject the proposed consent decree and close the
investigation.
After a year and a half of investigation, we have not been able to
identify any harm to consumers or competition as a result of actions by
Pool Corporation, Inc. (``PoolCorp''), and further investigation
appears unlikely to uncover such effects. As an initial matter, it is
important to note that, even accepting the allegations in the
complaint, PoolCorp did not engage in a general pattern of exclusionary
conduct. Rather, the complaint alleges that PoolCorp threatened
manufacturers not to supply an entering distributor in various local
markets. There is no allegation that PoolCorp sought to restrict supply
to (1) incumbents in any of these local markets, (2) established
distributors seeking to expand into markets dominated by PoolCorp, or
(3) established distributors in any of the dozens of other local
markets across the country.
The limited scope of PoolCorp's alleged exclusionary conduct is, of
course, no defense. PoolCorp's alleged threats to manufacturers, had
they been successful, may well have violated the antitrust laws. But
that is not what happened. The investigation revealed that PoolCorp's
demands were not honored by manufacturers. Instead, the evidence showed
that manufacturers made unilateral decisions not to supply the de novo
entrants in the various local markets.
There were legitimate reasons for pool equipment manufacturers not
to sell to these entrants. A manufacturer will typically accept a new
distributor only if the distributor will add to the value of the
distribution network by, for example, improving growth opportunities or
increasing promotional activities. Manufacturers often require a de
novo entrant to have adequate facilities, a history of successful
operations, and a favorable credit history before supporting it. In
this case, many of the allegedly excluded de novo entrants did not
satisfy these requirements. The lack of evidence establishing causation
between PoolCorp's requests and action by the manufacturers, combined
with plausible justifications for the manufacturers' actions, should be
fatal to this case.
Another problem with this case is that no entrants were actually
excluded.\11\ That is because the entrants were able to obtain supplies
from other manufacturers or distributors. The only claim to the
contrary is in Paragraph 28 of the complaint, which alleges that in
Baton Rouge, ``the new entrant's business ultimately failed in 2005''
because of the lack of ``direct access to the manufacturers' pool
products.'' The complaint neglects to mention that this entrant was
able to secure supplies from other sources and later sold itself to an
established out-of-state distributor. Since then, that distributor,
which has had full access to supplies, has been a highly effective
rival to PoolCorp. Thus, to the extent PoolCorp's threats had an effect
in Baton Rouge, they may have led to more, not less, competition.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\11\ The majority statement purports to be based on the
Complaint. However, the majority statement ignores the central
theory of the Complaint--exclusion of rivals through foreclosure of
supply (Complaint ]] 18-28)--and does not assert that any rivals
were actually excluded. Instead, the majority statement focuses on
an alternative theory of competitive harm--raising rivals' costs--on
which the Complaint offers scant details. (Complaint ]] 29-31.) As
support for this theory, the majority statement relies on an article
by Krattenmaker and Salop. See Thomas G. Krattenmaker & Steven C.
Salop, Anticompetitive Exclusion: Raising Rivals' Costs to Achieve
Power Over Price, 96 Yale L.J. 209, 224 (1986). As these authors
note, however, a raising rivals' costs strategy is unlikely to be
successful in a market with low entry barriers. Id. at 225 (entry
must ``be difficult''), 236 n.85 (``Obviously, some barriers to
entry and expansion must exist for price to rise.''). Here, neither
the complaint nor the majority statement alleges that there are any
significant barriers to entry in this industry.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
A third problem with this case is that there was no consumer
injury. The investigation did not uncover price increases, service
degradation, or other anticompetitive effects in any local markets.\12\
Economic analysis corroborated these results and suggested that even if
PoolCorp had completely foreclosed its rivals, the pricing effects
would have been minimal. The lack of consumer harm should not be
surprising given that PoolCorp's actions, at most, raised the costs of
a single competitor in each local market, without affecting other
incumbents or the entry prospects of established, out-of-market
dealers.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\12\ The basis for the majority statement's claim that there was
``substantial'' consumer harm resulting from the alleged conduct of
Respondent is a mystery. The complaint contains no factual
allegations of any harm to consumers, much less ``substantial''
harm. Likewise, there are no factual allegations in the complaint
corroborating the majority's claim that consumers ``had fewer
choices and were forced to pay higher prices for pool products.''
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The lack of consumer injury is also corroborated by the very low
entry barriers in this industry. Opening a pool supply distributorship
requires access to one or more of the major equipment suppliers, a few
trucks, a medium-sized warehouse, access to credit, and no more than
ten employees. There are hundreds of profitable pool supply
distributors, and entry and expansion are frequent events. Thus, any
effort to exclude a competitor would become a game of whack-a-mole: As
soon as one competitor is driven from the market, another would pop up.
Accordingly, I cannot find that there is a ``reason to believe''
that a violation occurred or that accepting the proposed consent decree
would be in the public
[[Page 72928]]
interest. 15 U.S.C. 45(b). Furthermore, I question whether this
investigation represented a wise use of Commission resources,
particularly given the austere climate in which we are operating. Even
accepting all of the allegations in the complaint as true, the likely
consumer injury would have amounted to just a few thousand dollars.
[FR Doc. 2011-30435 Filed 11-25-11; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6750-01-P