Frequency Regulation Compensation in the Organized Wholesale Power Markets, 67260-67285 [2011-27622]
Download as PDF
67260
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 210 / Monday, October 31, 2011 / Rules and Regulations
frequency regulation service provided
by a resource when the resource is
accurately following the dispatch signal.
DATES: Effective Date: This Final Rule
will become effective December 30,
2011.
DEPARTMENT OF ENERGY
Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission
18 CFR Part 35
[Docket Nos. RM11–7–000 and AD10–11–
000; Order No. 755]
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
Frequency Regulation Compensation
in the Organized Wholesale Power
Markets
Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission, DOE.
ACTION: Final rule.
AGENCY:
Pursuant to section 206 of the
Federal Power Act, the Commission is
revising its regulations to remedy undue
discrimination in the procurement of
frequency regulation in the organized
wholesale electric markets and ensure
that providers of frequency regulation
receive just and reasonable and not
unduly discriminatory or preferential
rates. Frequency regulation service is
one of the tools regional transmission
organizations (RTOs) and independent
system operators (ISOs) use to balance
supply and demand on the transmission
system, maintaining reliable operations.
In doing so, RTOs and ISOs deploy a
variety of resources to meet frequency
regulation needs; these resources differ
in both their ramping ability, which is
their ability to increase or decrease their
provision of frequency regulation
service, and the accuracy with which
they can respond to the system
operator’s dispatch signal.
The Commission finds that current
frequency regulation compensation
practices of RTOs and ISOs result in
rates that are unjust, unreasonable, and
unduly discriminatory or preferential.
Specifically, current compensation
methods for regulation service in RTO
and ISO markets fail to acknowledge the
inherently greater amount of frequency
regulation service being provided by
faster-ramping resources. In addition,
certain practices of some RTOs and ISOs
result in economically inefficient
economic dispatch of frequency
regulation resources.
By remedying these issues, the
Commission is removing unduly
discriminatory and preferential
practices from RTO and ISO tariffs and
requiring the setting of just and
reasonable rates. Specifically, this Final
Rule requires RTOs and ISOs to
compensate frequency regulation
resources based on the actual service
provided, including a capacity payment
that includes the marginal unit’s
opportunity costs and a payment for
performance that reflects the quantity of
srobinson on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
SUMMARY:
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:29 Oct 28, 2011
Jkt 226001
Robert Hellrich-Dawson (Technical
Information), Office of Energy Policy &
Innovation, 888 First Street NE.,
Washington, DC 20426, (202) 502–6360,
bob.hellrich-dawson@ferc.gov. Eric
Winterbauer (Legal Information), Office
of the General Counsel, 888 First Street
NE., Washington, DC 20426, (202) 502–
8329, eric.winterbauer@ferc.gov.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION:
UNITED STATES OF AMERICA
FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY
COMMISSION
Before Commissioners: Jon
Wellinghoff, Chairman; Marc Spitzer,
Philip D. Moeller, John R. Norris, and
Cheryl A. LaFleur.
Frequency Regulation Compensation
in the Organized Wholesale Power
Markets Docket Nos. RM11–7–000;
AD10–11–000
ORDER NO. 755
FINAL RULE
(Issued October 20, 2011)
1. Pursuant to section 206 of the
Federal Power Act (FPA),1 the
Commission is revising its regulations to
remedy undue discrimination in the
procurement of frequency regulation in
the organized wholesale electric markets
and ensure that providers of frequency
regulation receive just and reasonable
and not unduly discriminatory or
preferential rates. Frequency regulation
service is one of the tools regional
transmission organizations (RTOs) and
independent system operators (ISOs)
use to balance supply and demand on
the transmission system, maintaining
reliable operations. In doing so, RTOs
and ISOs 2 deploy a variety of resources
to meet frequency regulation needs;
these resources differ in both their
ramping 3 ability, which is their ability
1 16 U.S.C. 824e. Accord 16 U.S.C. 824d
(providing that rates must be just and reasonable).
2 The following RTOs and ISOs have organized
wholesale electricity markets: PJM Interconnection,
LLC (PJM); New York Independent System
Operator, Inc. (NYISO); Midwest Independent
Transmission System Operator, Inc. (MISO); ISO
New England Inc. (ISO–NE); California Independent
System Operator Corp. (CAISO); and Southwest
Power Pool, Inc. (SPP).
3 ‘‘Ramping’’ or the ability to ‘‘ramp’’ is
traditionally defined as the ability to change the
output of real power from a generating unit per
some unit of time, usually measured as megawatts
per minute (MW/min). A generator ramps up to
PO 00000
Frm 00002
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
to increase or decrease their provision of
frequency regulation service, and the
accuracy with which they can respond
to the system operator’s dispatch signal.
In this instance, the ability to provide
more accurate frequency regulation
service means to follow the system
operator’s dispatch signal more closely.
2. The Commission finds that current
frequency regulation compensation
practices of RTOs and ISOs result in
rates that are unjust, unreasonable, and
unduly discriminatory or preferential.
Specifically, current compensation
methods for regulation service in RTO
and ISO markets fail to acknowledge the
inherently greater amount of frequency
regulation service being provided by
faster-ramping resources.4 In addition,
certain practices of some RTOs and ISOs
result in economically inefficient
economic dispatch of frequency
regulation resources.
3. By remedying these issues, the
Commission is removing unduly
discriminatory and preferential
practices from RTO and ISO tariffs and
requiring the setting of just and
reasonable rates. Specifically, this Final
Rule requires RTOs and ISOs to
compensate frequency regulation
resources based on the actual service
provided, including a capacity payment
that includes the marginal unit’s
opportunity costs and a payment for
performance that reflects the quantity of
frequency regulation service provided
by a resource when the resource is
accurately following the dispatch signal.
I. Background
A. Frequency Regulation Service
4. Frequency regulation5 service is the
injection or withdrawal of real power by
facilities capable of responding
produce more energy and ramps down to produce
less. A storage device ramps up by discharging
energy and ramps down by charging. A demand
response resource, in the context of the provision
of frequency regulation, ramps up by consuming
less energy and ramps down by consuming more.
4 Both existing market participants and potential
entrants are affected by inefficient pricing. It is
possible that existing market participants would
offer faster ramping capabilities to the system
operator in response to a pricing scheme that
recognized such service.
5 Frequency regulation, or secondary frequency
control, is distinguishable from frequency response,
or primary frequency control, for the purposes of
this rulemaking. The latter, i.e., frequency response,
involves the automatic, autonomous and rapid
action of turbine governor control to change a
generator’s output and of demand response
resources to change consumption in automatic
response to changes in frequency. This occurs
independently of any dispatch signal from a system
operator. On January 20, 2011, the Commission
released for public comment a staff study evaluating
the use of frequency response metrics as a tool to
assess the reliability impacts of varying resource
mixes on the transmission grid.
E:\FR\FM\31OCR2.SGM
31OCR2
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 210 / Monday, October 31, 2011 / Rules and Regulations
srobinson on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
appropriately to a transmission system
operator’s automatic generator control
(AGC) signal. When dispatched
generation does not equal actual load
plus losses on a moment-by-moment
basis, the imbalance will cause the
grid’s frequency to deviate from 60
Hertz, the standard in the U.S. While
the system does deviate from 60 Hz in
the normal operation of the grid,
frequency deviations outside an
acceptable range negatively affect
energy consuming devices; major
deviations cause generation and
transmission equipment to disconnect
from the grid, in the worst case leading
to a cascading blackout. Frequency
regulation service can help to prevent
these adverse consequences by rapidly
correcting deviations in the
transmission system’s frequency to
bring it within an acceptable range.6
The system operator calibrates the AGC
signal sent to frequency regulation
resources to respond to actual and
anticipated frequency deviations or
interchange power imbalance, both
measured by area control error (ACE).
5. Today, frequency regulation is
largely provided by generators (e.g.,
water, steam and combustion turbines)
that are specially equipped for this
purpose. Provision by other resources is
emerging, as technologies develop and
tariff and market rules adapt to
accommodate new resources. For
example, the Texas Interconnection and
MISO currently use controllable
demand response in addition to
generators to provide frequency
regulation service. Such ‘‘regulation
capable’’ generation, storage devices,
and demand response resources can
respond automatically to signals sent by
the RTO or ISO, through AGC, to
increase or decrease real power
injections or withdrawals and thereby
correct actual or anticipated frequency
deviations or interchange schedule
imbalance, as measured by the ACE.
The faster a resource can ramp up or
down, the more accurately it can
respond to the AGC signal and avoid
overshooting.7 Alternatively, when a
resource ramps too slowly, its ramping
6 A balancing authority achieves acceptable
ranges by being in compliance with Control
Performance Standards 1 and 2 as defined in the
Commission-approved Reliability Standard BAL–
001–0.1a.
7 See Beacon Power Corporation (Beacon),
Technical Conference Speaker Materials, at Figure
3, which shows the difference between ISO–NE’s
ACE control signal, Beacon’s flywheel response,
and the allowable response rate under current ISO–
NE rules. Here, ‘‘allowable response rate’’ means
the rate at which the resource must respond to be
considered in compliance with the dispatch signal.
Frequency Regulation Compensation in the
Organized Wholesale Power Markets, Docket No.
AD10–11–000 (May 26, 2010).
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:29 Oct 28, 2011
Jkt 226001
limitations may cause it to work against
the needs of the system and force the
system operator to commit additional
regulation resources to compensate.
B. Current RTO and ISO Compensation
Practices
6. In the RTO and ISO markets,
compensation for frequency regulation
service is presently based on several
components. Depending on the RTO or
ISO, these payments include
consideration for capacity set aside to
provide the service 8 as well as some of
the following: the net energy that the
resource injects into the system;
accurately following the RTO’s or ISO’s
dispatch signal; and the absolute (rather
than net) amount of energy injected or
withdrawn. These payments are
intended to cover the range of costs
incurred in providing frequency
regulation service, e.g., operation and
maintenance costs, and loss of potential
revenue from foregone sales of
electricity.
7. The payment for capacity is
essentially an option payment to the
resource to keep a certain amount of
capacity out of the energy or other
markets in order to provide frequency
regulation service, typically based on a
market clearing price per MW of
capacity sold. ISO–NE, NYISO, MISO,
California ISO, and PJM incorporate into
this payment the opportunity cost of
foregone energy sales incurred by a
resource that provides frequency
regulation service. However, ISO–NE
and PJM do not apply the opportunity
cost payment uniformly to all cleared
resources, but rather make ex post
resource-specific opportunity cost
payments.
8. Compensation for frequency
regulation service also includes
payments or charges for the net energy
the resource injects into or withdraws
from the system. All RTOs and ISOs
currently provide a payment for the net
energy injected by a resource providing
regulation service during the operating
hour, calculated as the amount of energy
injected less energy withdrawn
multiplied by the real-time energy price.
9. Accuracy of performance can also
be incorporated into payments for
frequency regulation service. Currently,
NYISO incorporates accuracy into its
compensation for frequency regulation
service through a penalty that reflects
the accuracy with which the resource
follows its dispatch instruction.9 This is
8 This type of capacity payment is distinguishable
from capacity payments associated with the
procurement of resources to meet planning reserve
margin requirements.
9 NYISO, Ancillary Services Manual, Manual 2
(Nov. 2010), https://www.nyiso.com/public/
PO 00000
Frm 00003
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
67261
done through a performance index that
tracks how accurately a resource follows
the dispatch signal.10
10. ISO–NE makes payments for
frequency regulation service to reflect
the amount of work performed by a
resource by reflecting the absolute
amount of energy injected and
withdrawn, sometimes referred to as a
‘‘mileage’’ payment. Mileage payments
are intended to reward those resources
that perform more regulation service
instead of simply netting the total
amount of energy injected by the
resource.11
11. In general, when a resource
submits its frequency regulation bid to
the RTO or ISO, the bid is typically
required to include its ramp rate in
MW/min, its cost per megawatt-hours
(MWh) of ramping ability, and the total
capacity it is offering for frequency
regulation.12 The resource’s total
amount of capacity is based on and
limited by its ability to ramp up or
down.13 For example, a resource with a
relatively large amount of capacity, but
a relatively slow ramp rate would be
limited in how much capacity it could
offer as frequency regulation capacity. If
the resource can ramp one MW per
minute, it would only be able to offer
five MW of regulation capacity (for a
five minute dispatch) regardless of its
total capacity. On the other hand, a
smaller capacity, faster ramping
resource might not face such a
constraint. For instance, a storage device
that can hold a 20 MW charge and ramp
at 10 MW per minute, could offer its full
20 MW of capacity for five minutes.
12. The Commission recognizes that
some RTOs and ISOs are considering
changes to their frequency regulation
markets.14 For example, in February of
webdocs/documents/manuals/operations/
ancserv.pdf.
10 NYISO uses telemetry data to track how closely
a frequency regulation resource’s output is to the
dispatch signal. NYISO then adjusts the resource’s
payments to reflect its accuracy. For example, if the
resource’s response falls outside an acceptable
range 10 percent of the time, for a performance
index of 0.9, it will receive 90 percent of its
payment.
11 ISO–NE., Market Operations Manual M–11, at
3–11 (Dec. 2010), available at https://www.isone.com/rules_proceds/isone_mnls/m_11_market_
operations_revision_35_12_01_10.doc.
12 See, e.g., NYISO, Ancillary Services Manual,
Manual 2, at 4–8 (Nov. 2010).
13 A resource’s capacity is limited by the amount
it can ramp in five minutes because the system
operator in most RTOs and ISOs dispatch resources
every five minutes. CAISO dispatches every 10
minutes, and so a frequency regulation resource’s
capacity in that market is bound by the total
capacity it can ramp in 10 minutes.
14 In addition to the examples cited here, SPP is
in the process of developing its integrated
marketplace that will include a day-ahead market
and consolidated ancillary services market.
E:\FR\FM\31OCR2.SGM
31OCR2
67262
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 210 / Monday, October 31, 2011 / Rules and Regulations
this year PJM established a ‘‘Regulation
Performance Senior Task Force’’ to
examine the existing PJM regulation
market’s inability to distinguish
between resources’ various levels of
performance and the absence of
additional compensation for the
resources to perform at a high level once
they have qualified for the regulation
market.15 Therefore, the Commission
believes that this Final Rule is timely,
in that it will help guide these various
stakeholder processes.
C. Commission Inquiries Leading to This
Rulemaking
13. On May 26, 2010, the Commission
hosted a publicly noticed technical
conference 16 inviting various
stakeholders, including representatives
from the RTOs and ISOs, industry, and
academia to share their views on
whether current frequency regulation
market designs reflect the value of the
service provided, and whether the use
of faster-ramping resources for
frequency regulation has the potential to
provide benefits to the organized
markets.
14. On February 17, 2011, the
Commission issued a Notice of
Proposed Rulemaking in this
proceeding,17 seeking comment on its
proposal to require both a uniform price
for frequency regulation capacity paid to
all cleared resources as well as a
performance payment for the provision
of frequency regulation service, with the
latter payment reflecting a resource’s
accuracy of performance.18
II. Discussion
A. The Need for Reform
srobinson on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
15. As discussed below, the
Commission finds that current
frequency regulation compensation
practices in organized wholesale
electricity markets which fail to
compensate resources for all of the
service they provide as part of that
service are unjust, unreasonable, and
unduly discriminatory or preferential.
15 See PJM Regulation Performance Senior Task
Force Charter at 1 (2011) and ISO–NE., Report of
ISO New England Inc. Regarding the
Implementation of Market Rule Changes to Permit
Non-Generating Resources to Participate in the
Regulation Market, Docket No. ER08–54–014, at 5
(June 17, 2010).
16 See Final Agenda, Frequency Regulation
Compensation in the Organized Wholesale Power
Markets, Docket No. AD10–11–000 (May 26, 2010).
17 Frequency Regulation Compensation in the
Organized Wholesale Power Markets, 76 FR 11,177,
134 FERC ¶ 61,124 (2011) (NOPR).
18 See Appendix for a list of commenters.
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:29 Oct 28, 2011
Jkt 226001
1. NOPR Preliminary Finding
a. Unduly Discriminatory Pricing
16. In the NOPR, the Commission
stated that the current rules that govern
pricing and compensation for frequency
regulation services in RTOs and ISOs
may be unduly discriminatory, because
resources are compensated at the same
level even when providing different
amounts of frequency regulation
service.19
17. Specifically, the Commission was
concerned that under some existing
frequency regulation compensation
methods, resources may not be
compensated for all of the service they
provide even when given preference in
the dispatch order and asked to provide
more frequency regulation service than
other resources. The Commission noted,
for example, that CAISO, NYISO, MISO,
and PJM pay a capacity payment to all
resources that clear the frequency
regulation market, and then net the
amount of regulation up and regulation
down provided by these resources in
order to compensate for the energy costs
they incur. The Commission
preliminarily found that this
compensation method does not
acknowledge the greater amount of
frequency regulation service being
provided by faster-ramping resources.20
It stated that, as a result, slowerresponding resources are compensated
as if they are providing the same
amount of service when, in reality, they
are not,21 and that slower, larger
resources are being given a
compensatory advantage for their size
while faster, smaller resources do not
similarly receive compensation for their
ramping speed and actual service
provided.
18. The Commission also expressed
concern that the manner in which some
resources that provide frequency
regulation service are compensated for
19 NOPR,
134 FERC ¶ 61,124 at P 27.
simplified example would be to consider two
resources that clear with the same amount of
capacity and are directed to provide regulation up
and regulation down over the course of a fiveminute interval. The fast-ramping resource might be
directed to move around an initial output level up
five MW, then down three MW, up one MW, down
ten MW, and finally up nine MW. A netting
approach to compensation would determine that
the resource provided an additional two MW of
energy to the system (+ 5 ¥ 3 + 1 ¥ 10 + 9 = +
2) during that five minute interval. Meanwhile, a
slower-ramping resource may be directed to move
up three MW and then down one MW for a net of
two MW in relation to its initial output level. The
operator is not able to direct more movement
because the slower-ramping resource would not be
able to respond in the requisite time frame. Both
resources would receive identical compensation for
their movement, despite the first resource providing
more ACE correction.
21 NOPR, 134 FERC ¶ 61,124 at P 28.
20 A
PO 00000
Frm 00004
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
their opportunity costs 22 may be
unduly discriminatory.23 For instance,
while PJM provides an ex ante estimate
of opportunity costs that is included in
the uniform clearing price, it also
provides ex post ‘‘make whole’’
payments based on individual unit
opportunity costs, something that is not
reflected in the uniform market clearing
price calculation; 24 ISO–NE pays
opportunity costs on a resource-specific
basis so that the market-clearing price
for frequency regulation service does
not reflect any opportunity costs. Both
of these methods have the potential to
inefficiently select regulating resources
and also fail to reflect the marginal cost
(including opportunity cost) that
determines the market-clearing price
paid to all cleared suppliers. Therefore,
the NOPR proposed to require that all
resource bids include opportunity costs
and that all cleared frequency regulation
resources be paid the single market
clearing price, which reflects the total
marginal costs of the marginal cleared
unit.25
b. Potential Market Efficiency Gains
19. The NOPR also preliminarily
found that the use of faster-ramping
resources for frequency regulation has
the potential to improve operational and
economic efficiency and, in turn, lower
costs to consumers in the organized
markets. Faster-ramping resources may
be able to replace resources that
currently provide frequency regulation,
so that RTOs and ISOs may be able to
procure less regulation capacity, thereby
lowering costs to load.
2. Comments
a. Unduly Discriminatory Pricing
20. Many commenters expressly
support the NOPR’s proposed
performance payment to reflect the
amount of frequency regulation
provided by a resource.26 They
22 When participating in the energy and frequency
regulation markets, a resource is dispatched at a setpoint below its maximum capacity. Because this
amount of capacity is held in reserve to provide
frequency regulation, the resource misses the
opportunity to provide energy at the current LMP.
23 NOPR, 134 FERC ¶ 61,124 at P 31.
24 PJM, Manual 18: Operating Agreement
Accounting, at 12–16, available at https://
www.pjm.com/∼/media/documents/manuals/
m28.ashx.
25 NOPR, 134 FERC ¶ 61,124 at P 31.
26 A123, Alcoa, Beacon, CESA, Duke, ESA, EDF,
EPSA, ELCON, ENBALA, EnerNOC, Invenergy,
ISO–NE., Manitoba Hydro, MISO, MSCG,
NaturEner, NECPUC, NEPOOL, OMS, PaPUC,
PG&E, Powerex, Primus Power, PIOs, PJM, SoCal
Edison, Starwood/Premium, SunEdison, VCharge,
Viridity, and Xtreme Power all submitted comments
supporting the proposal to require a performance
payment. Some have offered alternative means to
accomplish the same goal, as described below.
E:\FR\FM\31OCR2.SGM
31OCR2
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 210 / Monday, October 31, 2011 / Rules and Regulations
srobinson on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
generally argue that for a frequency
regulation compensation mechanism to
be just and reasonable it must
compensate providers for the service
they actually provide to the grid. They
argue that the compensation systems
currently used in the RTOs and ISOs are
not only unduly discriminatory but also
problematic because they send
inefficient price signals. In addition,
they generally advocate that a
performance payment for regulation will
incent participants to offer more
flexibility to the system operator and
will compensate resources for the value
they provide the grid.27
21. Alcoa supports the proposal that
compensation for frequency regulation
service reflect the absolute (rather than
net) energy the resource injects into or
withdraws from the system. Alcoa states
that compensating for the amount of
movement creates strong market signals
because it ensures that those resources
that are performing more work to correct
system deviations are rewarded more. It
contends that this aligns with the
physical reality that the more the
resource is moved, the more wear will
occur on the equipment and the higher
the cost of supplying the service.28
22. Beacon contends that, currently,
all resources (except in ISO–NE),
regardless of how frequently they are
deployed or how much of the ACE
correction they provide, are paid the
same price per MW for their capacity
offered. Beacon contends that no
payment is based on how much the
resource is actually deployed to provide
frequency regulation.29 Beacon argues
that this is unjust and unreasonable.
Similarly, PIOs argue that NYISO’s and
MISO’s frequency regulation markets
fail to ensure just and reasonable
treatment of faster-ramping regulation
resources, and do not provide the
proper economic incentive for efficient
market participation.30
23. In order to illustrate the undue
discrimination that can occur in
frequency regulation markets, Beacon
provides data from its own 1 MW
flywheel operating in the ISO–NE
market, contending that these data
demonstrate that its resource provides
more than four times as much frequency
regulation service to ISO–NE as would
a 1 MW resource with an allowable
ramp rate of 1 MW/5 minutes.31 It
contends that the flywheel provides
0.48 MWh while the slower ramping
resource provides 0.11 MWh. Beacon
states that the reason its flywheel is able
to provide more frequency regulation
service is not just because of its faster
ramping ability, but also because it is
able to switch the direction of the
resource nearly instantaneously.32 In a
frequency regulation market paying only
a capacity payment, Beacon’s flywheel
will have performed a greater amount of
frequency regulation service, yet
received the same payment as the other
resource.
24. Beacon and ESA argue that a
performance payment system is needed
in order to send efficient price signals
and to compensate resources that are
asked to do more work. Beacon and ESA
maintain that this form of pricing will
appropriately compensate resources and
encourage the RTOs and ISOs to
improve operational and economic
efficiencies, thereby lowering costs to
consumers.33 In support of its
arguments, Beacon points to operating
data from its flywheel in NYISO
comparing the actual performance of its
flywheel to a hypothetical, similarly
sized slower resource to determine how
much each resource would contribute to
frequency regulation service.34 Beacon
states that even though the flywheel
would have been dispatched to provide
more than twelve times as much
frequency regulation service, its
flywheel would have actually been paid
less than the slower-responding
resource that provided less service to
the system.35
25. Beacon also provides an example
of five 20 MW resources with different
ramp rates—two average resources, two
27 See, e.g., EDF May 2, 2011 Comments at P 14
and P 16, CESA May 2, 2011 Comments at 2 and
8, ENBALA May 2, 2011 Comments at 8, ELCON
May 2, 2011 Comments at 4, Manitoba Hydro April
27, 2011 Comments at 2 (citing Prowse, D.
‘‘Improvements to a Standard Automatic Generation
Control Filter Algorithm’’ IEEE/PES Summer Power
Meeting, 92 SM 451–5 PWRS), OMS May 2, 2011
Comments at 6, Primus Power April 18, 2011
Comments at 5–6, PIOs May 3, 2011 Comments at
5–7, PJM May 2, 2011 Comments at 6, SoCal Edison
May 2, 2011 Comments at 3, Starwood/Premium
May 2, 2011 Comments at 4–5, Viridity May 2, 2011
Comments at 1, Xtreme Power May 2, 2011
Comments at 6–7.
28 Alcoa May 2, 2011 Comments at 3–4.
29 Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 20–21, ESA
May 2, 2011 Comments at 19–20.
30 PIOs May 2, 2011 Comments at P 16.
31 Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 6–7. These
data are the same data on which the table in
Appendix A of the NOPR is based.
32 Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 7.
33 Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 26–27, ESA
May 2, 2011 Comments at 24–25.
34 See Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 22–24.
35 Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 24 (citing
NYISO Tariff, Section 15.3.2.1(d), Regulation
Service Offers from Limited Energy Storage
Resources. ‘‘The ISO may reduce the real-time
Regulation Service offer (in MWs) from a Limited
Energy Storage Resource to account for the Energy
storage capacity of such Resource.’’). See also ESA
May 2, 2011 Comments at 21–23 (providing a
numerical example of how a two-part payment
system can result in cost savings in the
procurement of frequency regulation capacity and
service).
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:29 Oct 28, 2011
Jkt 226001
PO 00000
Frm 00005
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
67263
slower resources, and one faster
resource—that are dispatched and paid
based only on the amount of capacity
offered. Beacon asserts that if these
resources were to be paid for both
capacity and performance, the system
operator could reduce the amount of
capacity procured by 40 percent while
obtaining the same amount of regulation
service. Assuming a $10 decrease in the
capacity price and a $1.00/MW mileage
rate, Beacon estimates a reduction in
total regulation cost of 27 percent, in
addition to releasing 40 MW of
generation to provide energy or other
reserves.36
26. PJM states that it strongly supports
a performance-based methodology. PJM
claims that a performance payment
provides an appropriate incentive to
provide high quality regulation service
by tying a portion of the total
compensation to a resource’s
performance. In addition, PJM asserts
that a performance payment will ensure
resources provide accurate responses to
control signals, in contrast with the
current structure that provides no
incentive to perform above a minimum
threshold.37
27. Among the RTOs and ISOs, only
CAISO makes the claim that its markets
are not unduly discriminatory or
preferential. CAISO asserts that the
Commission cannot declare the existing
rate unjust and unreasonable or unduly
discriminatory based on an unsupported
conclusion that all markets require more
ACE correction.38 Indeed, CAISO argues
that its operational and reliability
requirements, including ACE correction,
have been and continue to be
adequately met by existing regulation
services and resources. Furthermore,
CAISO argues that its rates for
regulation apply to all resources equally
so long as the resource meets the
minimum operating and technical
requirements to provide regulation
because the amount of capacity a
resource may bid for regulation is based
upon the resource’s certified ramp rate
over a ten minute interval. It contends
that, therefore, a faster-ramping resource
can sell more regulation capacity than a
slower ramping resource. It argues that
these terms and conditions of service
provide comparable treatment for all
resources certified to provide
regulation.39 CAISO also argues that
while its energy management system
does not include a priority dispatch for
resources with faster-ramping
capability, its system will send control
36 Beacon
May 2, 2011 Comments at 33–36.
May 2, 2011 Comments at 6.
38 CAISO May 2, 2011 Comments at 6–7.
39 CAISO May 2, 2011 Comments at 8.
37 PJM
E:\FR\FM\31OCR2.SGM
31OCR2
srobinson on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
67264
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 210 / Monday, October 31, 2011 / Rules and Regulations
signals to faster ramping resources if it
requires a fast response to correct ACE.
Control signals are sent in part based on
a resource’s operating range and
ramping capability.40
28. Some commenters argue that the
Commission has failed to show a
sufficient basis for exercising its section
206 authority to mandate revisions to
existing RTO and ISO tariff
provisions.41 CAISO argues it has and
continues to meet its operational and
reliability requirements, and pays
equally all resources capable to meet the
requirement. As such, CAISO argues, its
markets are not unduly discriminatory
or preferential.
29. EEI contends that the Commission
has not shown that changing the
compensation mechanism to increase
compensation for faster ramping
resources will result in enhanced
reliability or enable system operators to
more easily meet reliability standards;
that the Commission is looking at only
one of the three elements of frequency
response (inertial response and governor
response being the others) and in doing
so has failed to provide the necessary
technical basis to demonstrate that its
assumptions that resources providing
frequency regulation are more valuable
than resources providing the other
services and that the resulting payments
are unduly discriminatory. Similarly,
NGSA argues that regulatory policies
that focus singly on special forms of
compensation and incentives for some
forms of ancillary and balancing
services, but not others, are likely to
result in distorted market signals and a
mix of services and products that are
sub-optimal for meeting system
balancing requirements. NGSA contends
that there is a direct interrelationship
between primary and secondary
frequency control, and compensation for
frequency regulation cannot be
considered in isolation.42
30. TAPS also argues that the existing
total compensation for frequency
regulation has not been shown to be
unjust and unreasonable. TAPS
contends that any increased payments
to faster-ramping resources must be
balanced by savings through reduced
regulation procurement or lower
payments to slower resources, such that
costs to consumers are reduced.43
31. Duke argues that the Commission
should not favor or subsidize one type
of resource over another.44 It contends
40 Id.
at 9.
May 2, 2011 Comments at 9–10, TAPS May
2, 2011 Comments at 5.
42 NGSA May 2, 2011 Comments at 4.
43 TAPS May 2, 2011 Comments at 5.
44 See also CAREBS May 2, 2011 Comments at 5–
6, AWEA May 2, 2011 Comments at 3–4, Duke May
41 EEI
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:29 Oct 28, 2011
Jkt 226001
that both fast- and slow-ramping
resources have a role to play and there
will be instances when operators will
not need faster-ramping resources to
address frequency deviations. As an
example, Duke states that there will be
a need for slower-ramping resources
that ramp with the load over a five
minute period (e.g., load following).45
32. EEI argues that the Commission
failed to support the NOPR proposal as
just and reasonable, because, according
to EEI, the Commission did not explain
how the two-part payment mechanism
will enhance reliability or make
compliance with reliability rules easier
or cheaper for system operators. EEI
claims that no substantial pilot
programs have been conducted to
evaluate the system cost and reliability
impacts of substituting non-traditional
resources for existing resources. EEI
suggests that the Commission encourage
the development of network pilot
programs before requiring a revision of
frequency regulation service.46
33. Several commenters express
concern that the Commission will act
prematurely, without a full record
addressing the various issues to which
the NOPR was addressed.47 For
example, NGSA, among others, cited
Commissioner Spitzer’s dissent to the
NOPR, arguing that feedback is needed
from a broad spectrum of industry
participants; otherwise the record on
which to make the proposed changes to
the Commission’s regulations may be
undermined.48 The NY TOs contend
that the record is insufficient to support
a conclusion that the NYISOadministered markets fail to adequately
compensate fast response resources.49
b. Potential Market Benefits
34. The primary economic benefit that
some commenters expect to see is
reduced costs of procuring frequency
regulation capacity, with a secondary
benefit of reduced energy costs.50
2, 2011 Comments at 4–5, ELCON May 2, 2011
Comments at 6, SoCal Edison May 2, 2011
Comments at 6.
45 Duke May 2, 2011 Comments at 4–6.
46 EEI May 2, 2011 Comments at 9.
47 CAISO May 2, 2011 Comments at 11–12, Duke
May 2, 2011 Comments at 2, EEI May 2, 2011
Comments at 10 (supported by Dayton, Detroit
Edison, and FirstEnergy), Jack Ellis May 2, 2011
Comments at 7, MISO TOs May 2, 2011 Comments
at 5.
48 Natural Gas Supply Association May 2, 2011
Comments at 5.
49 New York Transmission Owners May 2, 2011
Comments at 1.
50 See, e.g., Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 5,
ESA May 2, 2011 Comments at 3, EDF May 2, 2011
Comments at P 5–7, EDF May 2, 2011 Comments
at P 9, ENBALA May 3, 2011 Comments at 3,
NEPOOL May 2, 2011 Comments at 6, PaPUC May
2, 2011 Comments at 5, PJM May 2, 2011 Comments
at 3–4.
PO 00000
Frm 00006
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
Commenters argue that faster-ramping
resources are able to provide more
frequency regulation service from the
same amount of frequency regulation
capacity because faster-ramping
resources can provide more ACE
correction in real-time. Commenters
conclude that this will result in a
system operator needing to procure less
frequency regulation capacity.51
Commenters further explain that, as
these faster-responding resources
displace slower-ramping resources,
existing generators that are displaced
can be shifted to provide an even greater
amount of energy. These traditional
resources can then run at their full
capacity at their preferred steady-state
operating point which improves their
heat rate and reduces the wear and tear
on their equipment, thereby lowering
their cost to operate.52
35. Commenters cite several studies to
support the argument that fasterresponding resources will result in
economic benefits. Among them is
PNNL’s study showing that fast-ramping
energy storage resources (such as
flywheels and batteries) could be as
much as 17 times more effective than
conventional ramp-limited regulation
resources because of how quickly and
accurately they respond to a system
imbalance; 53 and a California Energy
Commission study which showed that
‘‘on an incremental basis, storage can be
up to two to three times as effective as
adding a combustion turbine to the
system for regulation purposes.’’ 54
36. Commenters also pointed to ISO–
NE and NYISO as examples of markets
that have a relatively high number of
faster-responding frequency regulation
resources. In both cases, the system
operator is able to procure a relatively
smaller amount of frequency regulation
capacity, compared to other RTOs and
ISOs. Beacon notes that ISO–NE. the
only RTO or ISO to both dispatch fasterramping resources first and then
compensate resources based on
performance, is able to procure the least
frequency regulation capacity, measured
51 SoCal
Edison May 2, 2011 Comments at 3.
May 2, 2011 Comments at 11, CESA
May 2, 2011 Comments at 5, ENBALA May 3, 2011
Comments at 4, ESA May 2, 2011 Comments at 11,
and PaPUC May 2, 2011 Comments at 5 and
Snowberger Affidavit at 8.
53 Makarov, Y.V., Ma, J., Lu, S., Nguyen, T.B.,
‘‘Assessing the value of Regulation Resources Based
on Their Time Response Characteristics,’’ Pacific
Northwest National Laboratory, PNNL—17632, June
2008.
54 Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 8–9 (citing
KEMA, ‘‘Research Evaluation of Wind Generation,
Solar Generation, and Storage Impact on the
California Grid’’ (prepared for the California Energy
Commission), June, 2010).
52 Beacon
E:\FR\FM\31OCR2.SGM
31OCR2
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 210 / Monday, October 31, 2011 / Rules and Regulations
srobinson on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
as a percentage of peak load.55 EDF also
notes that ISO–NE and NYISO, two
balancing authority areas with relatively
high concentrations of faster-responding
resources, procure relatively less
frequency regulation capacity.56
37. ISO–NE agrees that fast-ramping
resources provide benefits in the
regulation market and states that the
participation of fast-ramping resources
in the New England regulation market is
a factor in New England’s low current
regulation requirement. ISO–NE also
states that all other things being equal,
faster response is clearly better than
slower response, for the reasons
explained in the NOPR. PJM also argues
the importance of procuring a mix of
frequency regulation resources, some of
which will have the ability to
sustainably maintain their response.57
Likewise, SoCal Edison states that the
use of faster-ramping regulation
resources, in conjunction with an
efficient regulation dispatch algorithm
and effective unit compliance with the
dispatch signal should reduce the total
amount of regulation capacity needed to
perform regulation service.58
38. PIOs state that PJM estimates that
a 10 percent or 20 percent reduction in
its frequency regulation capacity
procurement could result in a $25
million or $50 million, respectively,
reduction in costs to consumers. PIOs
state that this savings is large in
comparison to the modest software costs
required to implement these market
rules.59
39. To illustrate the potential benefits
of faster-ramping resources providing
frequency regulation service, Primus
Power extends the Beacon Power
example 60 to one that applies more
generally. Primus Power simulates the
output of both what they define as a
traditional resource and a fast-response
resource. Both resources were assumed
to have a capacity of 1 MW; the
traditional resource could ramp 1 MW
in 5 minutes, while the faster-response
resource could ramp faster, mimicking
the actual ability of a Primus Power
energy storage resource. Primus Power’s
result supports that of Beacon, with the
55 Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 9–10. See
also ESA May 2, 2011 Comments at 9–10.
56 EDF May 2, 2011 Comments at P 8.
57 PJM May 2, 2011 Comments at 4.
58 SoCal Edison May 2, 2011 Comments at 3.
59 PIOs May 2, 2011 Comments at P 20 (citing PJM
Staff, ‘‘Problem Statement,’’ Jan. 19, 2011), available
at https://www.pjm.com/∼/media/committeesgroups/committees/mrc/20110216/20110216-item05-regulation-resource-performance-problemstatement.ashx. The Problem Statement was
presented to the PJM Markets and Reliability
Committee, and led to the establishment of a PJM
Regulation Performance Senior Task Force.
60 Primus Power May 2, 2011 Comments at 2.
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:29 Oct 28, 2011
Jkt 226001
faster-responding resource following the
AGC signal nearly perfectly, while the
slower-ramping resource lags to the
point of working against needed ACE
correction.61 Primus Power claims that
this results in the faster-ramping
resource providing approximately 76
percent more ACE correction.62
40. Commenters also mention the
potential for reliability benefits
stemming from the NOPR proposal.
A123, Alcoa, Beacon, CESA, ESA, PIOs,
and PJM all state that system operators
can also expect to see reliability benefits
from the integration of more fasterresponding resources. PIOs state that the
integration of more faster-responding
resources will result in enhanced
reliability because their ability to more
quickly and accurately follow dispatch
instructions will allow the system
operator to better maintain system
balance. Further, PIOs state that the
concern over sustainability is
unfounded. First, PIOs state that there is
little reason to believe that fasterresponding resources will completely
displace traditional resources in the
short or near term. Second, PIOs state
that, given the short dispatch window
system operators use, i.e. 5 or 10 minute
dispatch intervals, storage systems can
be assured of maintaining appropriate
charge.63
41. Xtreme Power argues that the
advantages of fast response storage
systems is that they do not have
problems such as efficiency
degradation, emissions, exposure to
peaking fuel prices, accelerated O&M,
and typical siting issues. Xtreme Power
also states that fast response storage
systems do not require air quality
permits like conventional fossil-fired
generation resources, and can therefore
be deployed to satisfy RTO or ISO needs
for additional regulation service more
quickly than new fossil-fired
generation.64
42. A123 presents data from ERCOT
indicating that incorporating storage
resources capable of responding to a
‘‘ramp-focused’’ signal from the system
operator will result in net ACE
remaining within allowable NERC
standards 100 percent of the time (as
opposed to only 71 percent of the time
when relying on traditional resources
responding to a slower signal). A123
argues that this improvement will
provide the system operator with a
larger reliability margin. A123 presents
this analysis as an illustration of the
difference between traditional slower61 Id.
at 3.
at 5.
63 PIOs May 2, 2011 Comments at P 22–23.
64 Xtreme Power May 2, 2011 Comments at 4–5.
62 Id.
PO 00000
Frm 00007
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
67265
ramping, unlimited energy resources
and faster-ramping, limited energy
resources.65
43. Alcoa contends that the NOPR
proposal is likely to result in increased
efficient operation of demand side
resources and therefore a decrease in the
amount of resources dedicated to
frequency regulation service.66 Alcoa
contends that there are reliability
benefits from integrating more direct
load control demand response into
system operations because these
resources can ramp faster and therefore
help restore system frequency more
rapidly in the event of a system upset.
Alcoa states that because this response
can happen within seconds, it can help
avert cascading system instability.67
44. PJM states that the use of fasterramping resources will enhance system
control. Better control will then lead to
a reduction in uncompensated flows
imposed on the system by a given
balancing authority and will provide
better individual control by that
balancing authority.68
45. Beacon and ESA agree that the use
of faster-ramping resources can result in
reliability benefits, based on the
expectation that the United States will
add 145,000 MW of wind generation to
the grid over the next ten years. They
argue that this will result in increased
supply variability, requiring increased
system flexibility.69 In the same vein,
Beacon and ESA both cite CAISO’s 20
percent renewable portfolio standard
study, which showed that CAISO will
require an additional 37 percent of
regulation up and 11 percent of
regulation down in the summer
season.70
46. In addition Beacon and ESA assert
that NYISO expects to need increased
regulation and reserve resources as more
wind is integrated into its system.71
Beacon, CESA, and ESA also points to
the Commission-sponsored, Lawrence
Berkeley National Laboratory (LBNL)
65 A123
May 2, 2011 Comments at 6.
May 2, 2011 Comments at 5.
67 Id. at 4.
68 PJM May 2, 2011 Comments at 3.
69 Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 11–12, ESA
May 2, 2011 Comments at 11, (citing Rick Sergel,
President and CEO, North American Electric
Reliability Corporation, Executive Remarks, FERC
Technical Conference on Integrating Renewable
Resources into the Wholesale Electric Grid, March
2, 2009).
70 Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 12, ESA May
2, 2011 Comments at 11–12 (citing CAISO,
‘‘Integration of Renewable Resources: Operational
Requirements and Generation Fleet Capability at
20% RPS,’’ at 52, table 3.3 (2010), available at:
https://www.caiso.com/2804/2804d036401f0.pdf).
71 Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 12, ESA May
2, 2011 Comments at 11 (citing NYISO, ‘‘Integration
of Wind into System Dispatch White Paper,’’
October 2008).
66 Alcoa
E:\FR\FM\31OCR2.SGM
31OCR2
67266
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 210 / Monday, October 31, 2011 / Rules and Regulations
srobinson on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
report that identified reliability
concerns due to the declining frequency
responsiveness of the US
interconnections. In order to address
these reliability concerns, LBNL
recommends expanding the frequency
control capability of the RTO and ISO
interconnections using advanced
technologies such as energy storage.72
47. Certain commenters 73 argue that
the integration of additional fasterresponding resources into the mix of
frequency regulation resources will
result in environmental benefits. For
example, Beacon, CESA, and ESA cite to
a 2007 KEMA and an October 2008
Carnegie Mellon University study in
support. The KEMA study demonstrated
that continued reliance on thermal
generating units to meet increased
regulation requirements could actually
increase emissions of carbon dioxide
(CO2), nitrogen oxides (NOX) and other
pollutants, thereby defeating one of the
main benefits of wind generation.74 The
Carnegie Mellon University study
estimated that 20 percent of the CO2
emission reduction and up 100 percent
of the NOX emission reduction expected
from introducing wind and solar power
will be lost because of the extra ramping
requirements they impose on traditional
generation.75 Finally, CPUC states that
while the Commission’s proposal is
resource-neutral, it provides an
economic incentive for resources to
assist in reducing greenhouse gas
emissions, compensate for variability of
intermittent resources, and reduce costs
to consumers through decreased
regulation procurement requirements.76
48. Other commenters offer cautious
support. For example, while Duke
Energy concurs that the faster-ramping
resource should be compensated for the
actual amount of work that it performs,
it cautions that faster-ramping resources
may not always be needed, and that
micromanaging power swings with
72 Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 13–14, CESA
May 2, 2011 Comments at 6, ESA May 2, 2011
Comments at 13–14 (citing Joseph H. Eto, Use of
Frequency Response Metrics to Assess the Planning
and Operating Requirements for Reliable Integration
of Variable Renewable Generation Lawrence
Berkeley National Laboratory, LBNL–4142E, 2010,
available at https://certs.lbl.gov/pdf/lbnl-4142e.pdf).
73 See e.g., EDF May 2, 2011 Comments at P10.
74 Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 13, CESA
May 2, 2011 Comments at 5, and ESA May 2, 2011
Comments at 12–13 (citing KEMA, Emissions
Comparison for a 20MW Flywheel-based Frequency
Regulation Power Plant, May 18, 2007).
75 Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 13, ESA May
2, 2011 Comments at 13 (citing Katzenstein, W., and
Jay Apt. Air Emissions Due To Wind and Solar
Power. Environmental Science & Technology. 2009,
43, 253–258. (available at https://pubs.acs.org/doi/
pdf/10.1021/es801437t)).
76 CPUC May 2, 2011 Comments at 2–3.
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:29 Oct 28, 2011
Jkt 226001
faster resources may even result in overcontrol of the system.77
49. Some commenters argue that the
Commission has not justified the
increased costs that its compensation
proposal may impose on load serving
entities and other network integration
transmission service customers.78
Others state that the Commission failed
to consider the impact on customers,
who EEI states will ultimately bear the
greatest share of costs, by balancing
increased payments to faster ramping
resources with savings through reduced
regulation procurement or lower
payments to slower resources. As a
result, EEI argues, load will likely pay
more for regulation service without any
demonstrated reliability benefit or
decrease in the need for other
resources.79 NY TOs, for example,
request that the Commission require
NYISO to estimate the net savings to
consumers that would result if offering
incentives for increased participation by
dedicated frequency regulation
resources induces more traditional
capacity to shift away from the
regulation market and into the energy
market.80 NaturEner requests that the
Commission be vigilant against possible
unintended consequences, such as
increasing frequency regulation cost or
requiring a greater volume of frequency
regulation resources.
50. Invenergy cautions the
Commission to evaluate whether
alternative compensation structures, in
addition to being higher cost, will also
result in better quality regulation, lower
quantities of regulation, and improved
reliability.81
51. EPSA states that while it supports
RTOs and ISOs employing a mileage
component similar to that employed in
the ISO–NE regulation market, that
measure should be used to meet the
objectives of regulation service and not
require incremental performance levels,
which do not yield incremental
benefits.82 EPSA states that adequate
frequency is being achieved currently
under NERC ACE control standards
through reliability requirement CPS1 by
each of the RTO and ISO balancing
authorities. Thus, EPSA encourages the
Commission to recognize that payment
for enhanced performance should only
be made if there is a material need for
that performance.83 Duke agrees, stating
77 Duke
May 2, 2011 Comments at 7.
May 2, 2011 Comments at 12, TAPS May
2, 2011 Comments at 4–5; Invenergy May 2, 2011
Comments at 2–3.
79 EEI May 2, 2011 Comments at 12.
80 NY TOs May 2, 2011 Comments at 5.
81 Invenergy May 2, 2011 Comments at 2–3.
82 EPSA May 2, 2011 Comments at 7.
83 Id. at 6.
78 EEI
PO 00000
Frm 00008
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
that no study has been conducted that
indicates faster response is necessary for
reliable system operations.84 While
CAISO notes that it is considering
development of a performance payment
for regulation service, it cautions the
Commission against requiring a specific
performance payment absent a
conclusion that faster-ramping resources
are required in all markets.85
52. Jack Ellis contends that the
Commission’s proposal to require a
payment for performance has several
flaws that cannot be easily corrected.86
He argues that the first flaw is that the
rate is likely to be administrativelydetermined. Mr. Ellis contends that
there is no straightforward way for both
the mileage payment and the capacity
payment to be established through
competitive offers. Therefore, he argues,
the subjective judgment of the
Commission and the operators of RTOs
and ISOs will replace market forces in
determining the value of frequency
regulation service. Second, Mr. Ellis
argues that because the rate will be
administratively-determined, it will be
controversial and subject to litigation.
Third, Mr. Ellis contends that the
performance payment will increase
payments that must be recovered
through uplift, complicating existing
settlement procedures and efforts to
reduce uplift. Fourth, Mr. Ellis argues
that a performance payment will unduly
discriminate against existing
technologies that could respond faster
but for the presence of barriers that have
not, to date, presented themselves as
obstacles. He explains that these barriers
include the use of static ramp rates that
reflect typical performance under all
conditions rather than peak
performance under conditions that exist
at a point in time. Finally, Mr. Ellis
contends that multi-part offers require
complex rules to deter market
manipulation because it is difficult to
differentiate between legitimate and
illegitimate bidding behavior.87 Mr.
Ellis asserts that it is neither reasonable
nor cost-effective to pay a premium for
faster ramping capability in situations
where adequate ramping capability is
available to meet the grid operator’s
needs.88
53. TAPS recommends that the
Commission direct each of the affected
regions to evaluate its own frequency
regulation market rules, and change
them only if they make a regionally84 Duke
May 2, 2011 Comments at 2.
May 2, 2011 Comments at 11–12.
86 Jack Ellis April 12, 2011 Comments at 2.
87 Jack Ellis April 12, 2011 Comments at 2–3.
88 Id. at 3.
85 CAISO
E:\FR\FM\31OCR2.SGM
31OCR2
srobinson on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 210 / Monday, October 31, 2011 / Rules and Regulations
specific showing that the changes will
increase consumer welfare.89
54. Some commenters dispute the
position that the integration of more
faster-responding resources for
frequency regulation service will result
in lower costs to consumers. Jack Ellis
argues that, while it is possible that
RTOs and ISOs could reduce the shortterm cost of serving load by procuring
less regulation, long-term costs would
likely increase as supply resources that
are pushed out of the frequency
regulation market demand higher prices
in other joint product markets such as
capacity, energy, and other ancillary
services markets. Mr. Ellis argues that
this will happen because these
resources will be losing revenue and
will make up for that lost revenue by
bidding in at higher levels in these other
markets.90 Mr. Ellis concedes that longterm savings could accrue, but only if
resource adequacy requirements also
decrease by an equal or greater amount
or if the integration of more fasterresponding resources allows a reduction
in the amount of incremental resources
that must be procured to deal with
increases in variable generation.91
55. The NY PSC recognizes the
potential benefits of the NOPR proposal,
but it is uncertain what the cost and
benefits of any proposed changes to the
compensation mechanism would be
within the NYISO.92 Finally, PG&E
argues that while the benefits expected
by others might be seen, a cost-benefit
analysis is appropriate.93
56. EEI, NY TOs, TAPS and Invenergy
also express concern that the NOPR
proposal will result in increased costs to
load. EEI argues that load will likely pay
more for regulation service without any
demonstrated reliability benefit or
decrease in the need for other resources.
NY TOs requests that the Commission
require NYISO to estimate the net
savings that would result if the NOPR’s
compensation mechanism causes more
traditional capacity to shift away from
the frequency regulation market and
into the energy market.
57. CAISO states that while it has
conducted studies that indicate a
preliminary need for additional ramping
capability, the full scope of its intended
studies is not complete and the benefits
have not been quantified. CAISO claims
that studies conducted to identify
system needs under a 20 percent
renewable portfolio standard indicate a
89 TAPS
May 2, 2011 Comments at 2–3.
Ellis April 12, 2011 Comments at 6
(emphasis in original).
91 Id. at 7.
92 NY PSC May 2, 2011 Comments at 3.
93 PG&E May 2, 2011 Comments at 8.
90 Jack
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:29 Oct 28, 2011
Jkt 226001
potential need for dispatchable down
ramping capability. However, CAISO
argues that studies for a 33 percent
Renewable Portfolio Standard are still
ongoing, and that the Commission
should not impose a specific
compensation model for regulation
resources without quantifying the needs
and benefits of such a model.94
58. EPSA asserts that the argument
that slow resources work against the
system operator assumes a regulation
performance standard that exceeds
existing requirements. EPSA states that
RTOs and ISOs are currently required to
maintain ACE within acceptable limits
over a ten-minute period, consistent
with NERC standards (CPS1 and CPS2).
Because AGC signals are sent on a foursecond cycle, the benefits of fastramping resources that are realized
within that cycle, such as increased
ramping mileage, may not materially
improve the operator’s ability to
regulate ACE on a ten-minute basis.
EPSA argues that RTOs and ISOs
already design and adjust regulation
software to account for differing
characteristics of regulation resources,
and requiring increased payments is
therefore unnecessary.95
59. While MISO states that it supports
a mileage payment that compensates
regulating resources for the wear and
tear associated with performance, it also
contends that there is presently no
benefit to consumers within the MISO
system that would justify payment for
the provision of down regulation in
addition to the capacity payment such
market participants already receive.
MISO recommends that the Commission
continue to allow RTOs and ISOs to
address whether netting or some other
mechanism is appropriate to
compensate regulating resources.96
c. Standardization of Market Rules
60. Several entities further oppose a
uniform approach, arguing that existing
market rules are different in the various
RTOs and ISOs and disparate resources
available in those markets creates a
preference for a regional approach.97
While PJM and some other RTOs
support the goal of the proposed
regulation, stating that it will result in
more efficient price signals and more
accurate payment for the provision of
94 CAISO
May 2, 2011 Comments at 14–16.
May 2, 2011 Comments at 7–9.
96 MISO May 2, 2011 Comments at 6.
97 Detroit Edison May 2, 2011 Comments at 2–4.
Duke May 2, 2011 Comments at 203. EEI May 2,
2011 Comments at 13–14, IRC May 2, 2011
Comments at 8, MISO TOs May 2, 2011 Comments
at 5–7, NYISO May 2, 2011 Comments at 5–6, PG&E
May 2, 2011 Comments at 3–4, SCE May 2, 2011
Comments at 2, TAPS May 2, 2011 Comments
at 4–5.
95 EPSA
PO 00000
Frm 00009
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
67267
frequency regulation service, a subset of
the RTOs and ISOs seek flexibility to,
for example in the case of ISO–NE,
allow compensation for performance
using the ‘‘mileage’’ paradigm that has
been used since 2003.98 CAISO
contends that there is not a single
approach to incentivize resources to
provide faster-ramping service, nor a
single compensation scheme that fits all
markets. Instead, CAISO recommends
that the Commission direct RTOs and
ISOs to examine through their
stakeholder processes potential payment
mechanisms that will address the
Commission’s concerns.99 MISO adds
that if the Commission determines in
this Final Rule that compensation of
frequency regulation providers requires
further examination, the Commission
should allow each RTO and ISO to
develop the compensation mechanisms
that are best for its region.100 Duke and
the NY PSC argue that every RTO and
ISO has different operations and market
mechanisms, and each RTO and ISO
should determine fair and just
compensation methodologies for
frequency regulation resources,
including faster ramping ones, that are
specifically tailored for their market.101
61. Dominion recommends that,
instead of standardizing compensation
for frequency regulation, the
Commission should direct the RTOs and
ISOs to revise their frequency regulation
markets so that they appropriately value
faster-ramping resources. Dominion
states that each region operates
differently and that each RTO or ISO
and its stakeholders are in the best
position to develop changes to the
compensation mechanism.102
62. PG&E argues that accuracy
payments alone (without any up and
down mileage component) could be
equally effective in addressing the
Commission’s NOPR objectives, or
alternatively, there may be entirely
different approaches such as new
regulation ramp-rate constraints and
market components.103
63. Starwood/Premium supports the
Commission’s proposal for a
performance payment and recommends
that the Commission require that all
RTOs and ISOs have standardized tariff
provisions for the compensation of
frequency regulation resources. They
argue that a lack of standardization
98 ISO–NE May 2, 2011 Comments at 6. See also,
NECPUC May 2, 2011 Comments at 4, NEPOOL
May 2, 2011 Comments at 8–9.
99 CAISO May 2, 2011 Comments at 2.
100 MISO May 2, 2011 Comments at 7.
101 Duke Energy May 2, 2011 Comments at 2,
NYPSC May 2, 2011 Comments at 4.
102 Dominion May 2, 2011 Comments at 3–4.
103 PG&E May 2, 2011 Comments at 8–9.
E:\FR\FM\31OCR2.SGM
31OCR2
67268
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 210 / Monday, October 31, 2011 / Rules and Regulations
leads to inefficient long-term investment
and makes it more difficult for potential
market entrants to analyze the economic
viability of entering one market or
another.104 Xtreme Power seeks prompt
implementation of the NOPR’s proposed
reforms, recommending that the
Commission establish an expedited
timeline for RTOs and ISOs to comply
with the Final Rule.105
srobinson on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
3. Commission Determination
a. Unduly Discriminatory Pricing
64. After developing and reviewing an
extensive record in this proceeding
compiled through a technical
conference in which 11 experts in the
field participated and issuance of a
NOPR, and consideration of responsive
pleadings submitted by 53 commenters,
the Commission finds, pursuant to FPA
section 206, that existing market rules
for the compensation of frequency
regulation resources are unjust and
unreasonable, and unduly
discriminatory or preferential. Current
rules in the RTO and ISO tariffs which
govern pricing and compensation for
frequency regulation services in the
RTO and ISO markets are unduly
discriminatory, because resources are
compensated at the same level even
when providing different amounts of
frequency regulation service; existing
frequency regulation compensation
methods fail to compensate certain
resources for all of the service they
provide, even when the system operator
directs them to provide more frequency
regulation service than other resources.
65. Beacon, Primus Power, and others
argue and present evidence showing
that current market rules allow for
unduly discriminatory compensation
among frequency regulation resources.
Beacon provides data from its
operations in ISO–NE 106 and NYISO 107
showing that two resources being asked
to provide different amounts of
frequency regulation service in real-time
can be compensated at the same level.
Beacon shows that it is even possible for
the resource asked to provide more
service to be paid less. Primus Power
also provides evidence that resources
that have different ramping capabilities
can perform different amounts of
work.108 Given current market rules
these resources would not be
compensated in a way that reflects the
different amount of work they have
performed. Support for this proposal
104 Starwood/Premium
May 2, 2011 Comments
at 3.
105 Xtreme
Power May 2, 2011 Comments at 8.
106 Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 6–7.
107 Id. at 22–24.
108 Primus Power April 18, 2011 Comments at 5.
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:29 Oct 28, 2011
Jkt 226001
also comes from the RTOs and ISOs.
PJM states that a performance payment
provides an appropriate incentive to
provide high quality regulation service
by tying a portion of the total
compensation to a resource’s
performance. In addition, PJM asserts
that a performance payment will ensure
resources provide accurate responses to
control signals, in contrast with the
current structure that provides no
incentive to perform above a minimum
threshold. We are convinced by the
evidence presented by commenters that
current market designs can result in
rates that are unduly discriminatory and
unjust and unreasonable.
66. As such, compensating resources
for their capacity without compensating
for the different amounts of frequency
regulation service different resources
provide fails to compensate for the
additional work performed by the
resources. Thus, contrary to CAISO’s
position that its market rules are not
unduly discriminatory or preferential
because they allow a faster-ramping
resources to offer a relatively greater
amount of capacity into the regulation
market than a slower ramping resources
with the same capability, we find that
this fails to differentiate between the
different amounts of frequency
regulation service different resources
provide, and therefore fails to
compensate for the additional work one
resource may be asked to do by the
system operator compared to another
resource. In this respect, CAISO’s
market design is no different from other
RTOs and ISOs in that it compensates
frequency regulation resources in a
manner we find to be unduly
discriminatory.109
67. Where the Commission finds an
existing rate to be unjust, unreasonable,
unduly discriminatory, or preferential,
the Commission has a statutory mandate
to set the just and reasonable rate.110
The Commission agrees with
commenters who argue that current
methods used by RTOs and ISOs to
compensate frequency regulation
providers that fail to account for the
actual service provided by resources are
unduly discriminatory and that a
resource’s performance in following the
AGC signal of the RTO or ISO should be
taken into consideration when
compensating that resource for
providing frequency regulation service.
We find that including a performance
payment system will ensure just and
109 This is irrespective of whether the energy
management system includes a priority dispatch for
resources with faster-ramping capability or the
system dispatcher sends control signals to the
resource.
110 16 U.S.C. 824e.
PO 00000
Frm 00010
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
reasonable rates, based on the actual
service provided at costs established by
competitive processes, and resulting in
efficient price signals and appropriately
compensating resources that are asked
to do more work. 111
b. Potential Market Benefits
68. The Commission’s setting of a just
and reasonable rate here is further
supported by the many comments
received in response to the NOPR’s
contention that faster responding
resources have the potential to improve
the operational and economic efficiency
of the frequency regulation market.
Commenters point to the more efficient
utilization of all resources capable of
providing frequency regulation when
the payment to resources is structured
to justly compensate resources for the
work performed, thus freeing other
resources to perform services more in
line with their operational
characteristics and increasing the
efficiency of doing so. We find these
comments persuasive. A123, Beacon,
PNNL, CESA and ESA provide evidence
demonstrating that faster-responding
resources have the potential to lower
frequency regulation capacity
requirements, thereby improving market
efficiencies. Further, experience in the
organized markets that already have
higher concentrations of fasterresponding resources shows that less
frequency regulation capacity
procurement is required due to the
availability of faster-responding
resources to provide that capacity.112
69. We are not persuaded by
commenters, like EEI, that argue that the
Commission should encourage pilot
programs to measure reliability benefits
before adopting the NOPR proposal.
First, we note that ISO–NE has carried
out just such a pilot program.113
111 See Promoting Wholesale Competition
Through Open Access Non-Discriminatory
Transmission Services by Public Utilities; Recovery
of Stranded Costs by Public Utilities and
Transmitting Utilities, Order No. 888, 61 FR 21540
(May 10, 1996), FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,036 at
31,684 (1996), order on reh’g, Order No. 888–A, 62
FR 12274 (Mar. 14, 1997), FERC Stats. & Regs.
¶ 31,048, order on reh’g, Order No. 888–B, 81 FERC
¶ 61,248 (1997), order on reh’g, Order No. 888–C,
82 FERC ¶ 61,046 (1998), aff’d in relevant part sub
nom. Transmission Access Policy Study Group v.
FERC, 225 F.3d 667 (DC Cir. 2000), aff’d sub nom.
New York v. FERC, 535 U.S. 1 (2002). (‘‘In the
context of an emerging competitive market in
generation, discriminatory practices that once did
not constitute undue discrimination must be
reviewed to determine whether they are being used
to prevent the benefits of competition in generation
from being achieved.’’).
112 Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 9–10, ESA
May 2, 2011 Comments at 9–10, EDF May 2, 2011
Comments at P 8.
113 See ISO–NE, Market Rule 1, Appendix J,
Alternative Technologies Regulation Pilot Program,
E:\FR\FM\31OCR2.SGM
31OCR2
srobinson on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 210 / Monday, October 31, 2011 / Rules and Regulations
Second, the Commission has
determined that it must act to remedy
undue discrimination in the current
compensation for frequency regulation;
the Commission is ensuring just and
reasonable rates and protecting against
undue discrimination among resources
in doing so. It is irrelevant to this
finding that the RTOs and ISOs
currently comply with the relevant
NERC standards, as argued by EPSA.
EPSA’s argument does not take away
from the unduly discriminatory way in
which the RTOs and ISOs compensate
the resources that they procure in order
to meet the NERC reliability standards.
The reforms required here are necessary
to remedy unduly discriminatory rates,
but they will also enable greater
competition in the organized markets
and allow existing generation to provide
more capacity in the energy markets and
to run closer to their optimal output
levels.
70. Contrary to EEI’s arguments, the
justness and reasonableness of the
compensation mechanism directed here
does not hinge on a finding that it will
improve reliability. It is important to
note, however, as discussed in the
comments submitted by PJM, a
resource’s ability to quickly and
accurately follow dispatch instructions
will allow the system operator to better
maintain system balance.114
71. We also disagree with the
contention that, while short-run costs
might decrease, long-run costs will
increase due to displaced frequency
regulation resources demanding higher
prices in the energy market to make up
for their lost frequency regulation
revenue. There is no reason to believe
that energy costs would increase when
the supply of available energy capacity
increases. If markets currently clear
with a sufficient level of capacity,
adding new capacity at a higher cost
would not change that and would not
lead to higher market-clearing prices in
the energy market. Any market
participant that chooses to raise its offer
price runs the risk of its capacity not
clearing in the energy market. And
because energy resources would be able
to operate at more efficient heat rates,
they would be able to offer their
capacity into the energy markets at a
lower price.
72. We find persuasive the arguments
made by commenters that we can expect
to see market efficiency gains and
available at https://www.iso-ne.com/regulatory/
tariff/sect_3/mr1_append-j.pdf. The most recent
informational filing from ISO–NE describing this
program can be found at https://elibrary.ferc.gov/
idmws/common/opennat.asp?fileID=12768589
(Sept. 19, 2011).
114 PJM May 2, 2011 Comments at 3–4.
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:29 Oct 28, 2011
Jkt 226001
reduced costs to consumers. For
example, Beacon, ESA, Alcoa, Primus
Power, and other commenters argue
convincingly that sending efficient price
signals will remove barriers to the entry
of faster-ramping and more accurate
frequency regulation resources. This in
turn should lead to reductions in the
amount of frequency regulation capacity
that each balancing area authority needs
to procure in order to maintain
reliability. As the needed quantity of
frequency regulation decreases, the net
result should be a reduction in
expenditures on frequency regulation,
and ultimately a lower cost for
electricity for consumers.115
Commenters cite studies from PNNL,
the California Energy Commission, and
PJM, and data from ISO–NE and NYISO,
that support this conclusion. PNNL
showed that faster-ramping frequency
regulation resources could be as much
as 17 times more effective than
conventional ramp-limited regulation
resources 116 and the California Energy
Commission found that storage
resources can be up to two to three
times as effective as adding a
combustion turbine to the system for
regulation purposes.117 In addition,
Xtreme Power notes that many newer
technologies can operate in the
frequency regulation market at lower
costs than other, older technologies.118
Therefore, we expect lower costs for
consumers will result because less total
capacity must be procured and because
the capacity that is procured will be
from lower-cost resources entering the
market. Further, we share the view that
the displacement of existing resources
may result in those resources being able
to more efficiently operate in the energy
markets, submitting lower offers to
supply energy, and thereby lowering
costs to consumers in that market.
Further, in the long-run, efficient price
signals will also incent the efficient mix
of resources to enter the market, thereby
leading to lower long-run costs to
consumers. We note that many
commenters also cite potential
reliability 119 and environmental 120
115 Primus
Power May 2, 2011 Comments at 7.
116 Makarov, Y.V., Ma, J., Lu, S., Nguyen, T.B.,
‘‘Assessing the value of Regulation Resources Based
on Their Time Response Characteristics,’’ Pacific
Northwest National Laboratory, PNNL—17632, June
2008.
117 Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 8–9 (citing
KEMA, ‘‘Research Evaluation of Wind Generation,
Solar Generation, and Storage Impact on the
California Grid’’ (prepared for the California Energy
Commission), June, 2010).
118 Xtreme Power May 2, 2011 Comments at 5.
119 See generally A123, Alcoa, Beacon, CESA,
ESA, PIOs, and PJM.
120 See generally Beacon, CESA, CPUC, ESA, and
EDF.
PO 00000
Frm 00011
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
67269
benefits that could be seen from the use
of faster-ramping resources. Thus, we
find that the changes mandated by this
Final Rule will not only remedy the
undue discrimination existing in
current market designs, but have the
potential to result in lower costs to
consumers.
73. While Duke argues that fasterramping resources may not always be
needed to ensure the reliability of the
system, and that the markets are
currently operating without
performance payments, the Commission
finds that adding a performance
payment to the compensation system
will remedy undue discrimination and
improve the efficiencies in the market
and allow resources to provide those
services that best suit them. Resources,
no matter their type, will only receive
the performance payment when they are
actually called on to provide frequency
regulation service, and they do so
accurately. We also reject MISO’s
recommendation that we allow RTOs
and ISOs to continue to only net energy
balances and provide a capacity
payment as compensation for frequency
regulation service. As we state above,
doing so can result in unduly
discriminatory treatment of frequency
regulation resources.
74. MISO’s claim that its customers
derive no benefit from down regulation
is based on the presumption that MISO
never directs any regulation resources to
provide frequency regulation in that
direction. Even if this is true, and MISO
provided no data showing that it is, it
does not change the fact that relying
only on the capacity payment and net
energy balancing results in
discriminatory compensation when one
resource is asked to provide more
movement than others, a situation that
can occur even if MISO only ever
directs its resources to provide up
regulation. Accordingly, as discussed
further in the compliance section below,
we will require the ISOs and RTOs to
include a performance payment in their
frequency regulation pricing
mechanism.
c. Standardization of Market Rules
75. In response to certain commenters
express concerns with requiring a
uniform approach to compensation for
frequency regulation, as described
below, we will allow the RTOs and ISOs
flexibility to design market rules that
accommodate their markets, while at the
same time addressing existing unduly
discriminatory rates. In response to
Starwood/Premium, it is not practical
for the Commission to mandate that all
RTOs and ISOs have identical
provisions in their tariffs for the
E:\FR\FM\31OCR2.SGM
31OCR2
67270
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 210 / Monday, October 31, 2011 / Rules and Regulations
compensation of frequency regulation
resources. First, the RTOs and ISOs do
not now have identical provisions for
other market operations; mandating
identical provisions in this regard could
require completely overhauling all RTO
and ISO tariffs. Second, identical tariff
provisions are not necessary so long as
all tariffs provide for just and reasonable
and not unduly discriminatory or
preferential rates.
76. PG&E suggests that an accuracy
component alone could suffice to
remedy undue discrimination in the
compensation of frequency regulation
resources. While this would account for
the difference in the accuracy of
resources, it would fail to acknowledge
the different levels of work requested of
each. Further, the Final Rule does not
create a special class of resource or
otherwise compensate any one type of
resource to the exclusion of others. This
Final Rule is resource-neutral, requiring
that compensation reflect the frequency
regulation service provided, no matter
the resource.
77. Thus, we will require certain
things of all RTOs and ISOs: to institute
a two-part payment for frequency
regulation and to account for a
resource’s accuracy in its compensation.
However, as described below, in many
instances we will leave to the individual
RTOs and ISOs how best to meet these
requirements.
srobinson on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
B. Specific Proposals
78. The NOPR set forth a frequency
regulation compensation mechanism for
the RTO and ISO markets to ensure that
pricing and compensation of frequency
regulation service is just and reasonable
and not unduly discriminatory or
preferential. Specifically, the
Commission proposed to require RTOs
and ISOs to change their tariffs so that
regulation resources receive a two-part
payment. The first part of the payment
is a capacity, or option, payment to have
a certain amount of capacity held in
reserve and not participate in the energy
market in order to provide frequency
regulation service. To produce the
efficient market outcome, this proposed
payment includes the marginal
regulating resource’s opportunity costs.
The NOPR also set forth a second
payment based on performance, as
measured by the amount of MWh up
and down movement the resource
provides in response to the system
operator’s dispatch signal.121 This
performance payment takes into
121 This applies whether an RTO or ISO allows
resources to sell regulation up and regulation down
separately or requires resources to offer both
regulation up and down as one product.
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:29 Oct 28, 2011
Jkt 226001
consideration a resource’s accuracy in
responding to that signal. The
Commission preliminarily found that
this compensation structure is necessary
to ensure that pricing schemes for
frequency regulation service in the
organized wholesale electricity markets
result in rates that are just and
reasonable, and not unduly
discriminatory or preferential.
1. Capacity Payment and Opportunity
Cost
a. NOPR Proposal
79. The Commission proposed to
require that each regulating resource be
paid a uniform capacity payment that
includes the opportunity cost of the
marginal regulating resource. As
discussed above, some RTOs and ISOs
currently pay resource-specific
opportunity costs or make-whole
payments in addition to a capacity
payment, while others incorporate the
marginal unit’s opportunity cost into a
uniform regulation market clearing
capacity price. In order to send an
efficient price signal to frequency
regulation resources, the Commission
proposed that RTOs and ISOs base the
clearing price for frequency regulation
on the marginal resource’s costs,
including opportunity cost. The NOPR
explained that paying a unit-specific
opportunity cost distorts the market by
basing the commitment of regulating
units on incomplete market information,
potentially leading to committing units
with higher costs than other units not
committed. This problem is especially
glaring in a market such as this where
some resources have no opportunity
costs, resulting in disparate payments to
resources.122 Accordingly, the
Commission preliminarily found that a
frequency regulation compensation
mechanism that includes a uniform
clearing price with accurately
determined opportunity costs will
reduce errors in selecting the optimal
portfolio of regulation suppliers each
hour (and each day), which reduces
total regulation costs to consumers and
ensures that rates are just and
reasonable and not unduly
discriminatory or preferential.
80. In addition, the Commission
preliminarily found that cross-product
opportunity costs 123 should be
122 For example, a storage resource that is only
allowed to participate in the frequency regulation
market has no opportunity costs related to the
energy market, unlike a traditional generator.
Therefore, the storage resource’s capacity payment
could be lower than the generator’s capacity
payment. These payments send inefficient signals
to market participants.
123 A cross-product opportunity cost, in this case,
is the revenue a regulation provider loses because
PO 00000
Frm 00012
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
calculated by the RTO or ISO, as it has
the best information to determine a
frequency regulation resource’s
opportunity cost due to not
participating in the energy market.
Further, the Commission proposed that,
where appropriate, resources should be
permitted to include inter-temporal
opportunity costs in their capacity
bid.124 The Commission sought
comment on its proposal to require each
regulating resource to be paid a uniform
capacity payment that includes the
opportunity cost of the marginal
regulating resource.
b. Comments
i. The Capacity Payment
81. A number of commenters support
the Commission’s capacity payment
proposal.125 They agree that this
proposal will result in a price signal that
will more efficiently select the portfolio
of resources between the energy and
regulation markets.126 OMS states that it
believes that when a consistent
definition of opportunity cost is used
and reflected in the market price, the
optimal solution for commitment and
dispatching across energy and reserves
is accomplished.127 Xtreme Power states
that it supports the NOPR’s proposal
because a uniform capacity payment
will help entice new entry into the
frequency regulation market, thereby
enhancing competition, whereas unitit is on stand-by to provide regulation and is not
providing energy or another product.
124 An inter-temporal opportunity cost represents
the foregone value when a resource must operate at
one time, and therefore must either forego a profit
from selling energy at a later time or incur costs due
to consuming at a later time. The trade-off
presented to thermal storage provides an example
of inter-temporal opportunity costs. A thermal
storage operator would prefer to ‘‘charge’’ (heat
bricks or freeze water) when prices are low. If such
a resource were to provide frequency regulation, it
could be asked to stop charging during low price
periods and then be forced to charge during high
price periods.
125 Alcoa May 2, 2011 Comments at 3, Beacon
May 2, 2011 Comments at 15–16, CESA May 2,
2011 Comments at 2, Dominion May 2, 2011
Comments at 4, Duke May 2, 2011 Comments at 6,
EDF May 2, 2011 Comments at 5, ELCON May 2,
2011 Comments at 2–4, EPSA May 2, 2011
Comments at 5, ENBALA May 2, 2011 Comments
at 8, ESA May 2, 2011 Comments at 16–18, IRC May
2, 2011 Comments at 7, ISO–NE May 2, 2011
Comments at 2 and 13, NEPOOL May 2, 2011
Comments at 7–8, NYISO May 2, 2011 Comments
at 2, OMS May 2, 2011 Comments at 4, PG&E May
2, 2011 Comments at 7, PJM May 2, 2011 Comments
at 5, Powerex May 2, 2011 Comments at 4, Primus
Power May 2, 2011 Comments at 6, SoCal Edison
May 2, 2011 Comments at 4, VCharge April 27,
2011 Comments at 2, and Xtreme Power May 2,
2011 Comments at 6.
126 Dominion May 2, 2011 Comments at 4,
ELCON May 2, 2011 Comments at 2–3,
127 OMS May 2, 2011 Comments at 4.
E:\FR\FM\31OCR2.SGM
31OCR2
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 210 / Monday, October 31, 2011 / Rules and Regulations
specific capacity costs, paid on a unitspecific basis, will distort the market.128
82. Beacon, CESA, EDF, PG&E,
Powerex, ENBALA, and ESA 129 agree
that the capacity payment should be
based on the marginal unit’s costs,
including its opportunity cost, in part
because, as some parties note, a large
part of a traditional resource’s cost to
provide frequency regulation is the lost
opportunity cost associated with not
providing energy. Several parties also
note that RTOs and ISOs that pay unitspecific opportunity costs send a
distorted market signal, possibly
resulting in a higher cost resource being
selected to provide service in lieu of a
lower-cost resource. These commenters
assert that a uniform capacity payment
that includes opportunity cost will send
the strongest price signal to low cost
resources, and that the grid should
experience a reduction in the overall
market costs as low cost providers are
encouraged to enter the market.130
Specifically, Beacon states that such a
payment will remove an economic
barrier to entry of new alternative
regulation technologies by ensuring that
the capacity payment reflects the full
value of that service.131
83. EPSA agrees that the most
efficient dispatch and fairest regulation
market design is one in which all
resources compete on the same basis for
the same price. EPSA states that the
regulation market should consider each
resource’s as-bid cost plus any
opportunity cost, such that the marginal
as-bid plus opportunity cost of the
resources selected should set a uniform
clearing price paid to all. It argues that
a uniform market clearing price will
ensure consideration of all appropriate
marginal costs for all regulation market
participants and will result in price
signals that will properly incent
efficient future infrastructure
investment.132
84. ENBALA notes that individual
side payments made to resources are
generally confidential and hidden in a
broader declaration of total payments,
only adding complexity and inefficiency
to the markets. On the other hand, it
states that an optimized total cost
solution that calculates a uniform price
128 Xtreme
Power May 2, 2011 Comments at 6.
May 2, 2011 Comments at P 12–13 (citing
Beacon Power June 25, 2010 Comments on May 26,
2010 Technical Conference (Docket No. AD10–11–
000) at 44–45), PG&E May 2, 2011 Comments at 7,
Powerex May 2, 2011 Comments at 4, Primus Power
April 18, 2011 Comments at 6.
130 Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 16, CESA
May 2, 2011 Comments at 7, ESA May 2, 2011
Comments at 16, EDF May 2, 2011 Comments at P
12–13.
131 Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 18.
132 EPSA May 2, 2011 Comments at 5.
srobinson on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
129 EDF
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:29 Oct 28, 2011
Jkt 226001
utilizing opportunity costs provides
transparency and clarity.133
85. PIOs state that not including
opportunity costs in a uniform clearing
price discriminates against newer
resources with lower opportunity costs
that, in a full marginal clearing price
auction, would generally be more
economic than traditional generators
with higher opportunity costs stemming
from operating at less than maximum
capacity.134 PIOs state that the proposed
method would ensure that the marketclearing capacity price would reflect the
total marginal costs of the last cleared
unit, thereby eliminating the unlevel
playing field that out-of-market
opportunity cost payments currently
impart.135
86. Beacon, CESA, and ESA note that
PJM has recently filed with the
Commission tariff revisions that will
alter how it calculates opportunity costs
for regulation capacity. In it’s filing, PJM
states that these revisions ‘‘[h]elp to
reduce after-the-fact, non-market
changes to Regulation resource
compensation, and enhance price
signals that will better enable new,
innovative resources and technologies
to meet the system’s Regulation needs
* * *.’’ 136 Beacon and CESA also
contend that PJM has acknowledged
that the value of frequency regulation
capacity has been upwards of 33 percent
higher than is reflected in market
clearing prices,137 a statement they
assert is supported by PJM’s market
monitor.138
87. EPSA argues that ISO–NE pays
unit-specific opportunity costs, which,
according to EPSA, risks understating
the regulation clearing price where a
unit with an opportunity cost is the
marginal resource.139 Beacon, CESA,
and ESA also note that at the technical
conference, ISO–NE stated that it is
moving in the direction of paying a
uniform clearing price.140 Beacon, ESA,
CESA, and NEPOOL state that at the
133 ENBALA
May 3, 2011 Comments at 8.
May 2, 2011 Comments at P 7.
135 Id. P 12.
136 Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 17, CESA
May 2, 2011 Comments at 7, ESA May 2, 2011
Comments at 16–17 (citing PJM’s Proposed Package
of Reforms to Establish Just and Reasonable Pricing
for Operative Reserve Shortages in the PJM Region
(Docket No. ER09–1063–004) at 3).
137 Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 18 (citing
Monitoring Analytics, LLC. ‘‘2010 State of the
Market Report for PJM.’’ March 10, 2011).
138 Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 18–19, ESA
May 2, 2011 Comments at 17–18 (citing Monitoring
Analytics, LLC. ‘‘2010 State of the Market Report for
PJM.’’ March 10, 2011).
139 EPSA May 2, 2011 Comments at 5.
140 Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 17, CESA
May 2, 2011 Comments at 7, ESA May 2, 2011
Comments at 17 (citing Transcript of May 26, 2010
Technical Conference at 149 (lines 15–16)).
134 PIOs
PO 00000
Frm 00013
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
67271
November 2010 NEPOOL Markets
Committee meeting ISO–NE stated that
a ‘‘uniform clearing price provides more
efficient long run investment
signals.’’ 141 NEPOOL states that ISO–
NE indicated that it is open to
considering the Commission’s proposal
for rules that would include opportunity
costs in the uniform capacity payment,
and that it was in the process of
evaluating market rule changes that
would accomplish this goal.142
88. At the same time, some
commenters express concerns regarding
the inclusion of opportunity costs in the
market clearing price for frequency
regulation capacity. In general, Duke
agrees with the Commission’s proposal
to require the market clearing price for
frequency regulation capacity to be
uniform and reflect the marginal
clearing unit’s opportunity costs.
However, Duke argues that it is
uncertain how some storage devices
would fit into a capacity payment
mechanism. For instance, for a resource
that is charging part of the time and
discharging part of the time, Duke
believes that when this resource is
charging (i.e. acting like a load), it
should not receive a capacity
payment.143
89. NEPOOL and IRC request that the
Final Rule afford ISO–NE and
stakeholders sufficient flexibility to
develop a solution that accomplishes
the Commission’s goals, given the
current market design’s consistency
with the NOPR proposal and
circumstances in the region.144
90. SoCal Edison argues that, while
the CAISO day-ahead market is efficient
in that it incorporates opportunity costs
into a uniform clearing price for
frequency regulation capacity, the realtime market has difficulties capturing
inter-temporal opportunity costs due to
its limited look-ahead time frame.145
91. PIOs recommend that after
implementing the NOPR’s proposed
compensation approach in the RTOs
and ISOs, the Commission should
consider whether the capacity payment
component of the method remains
appropriate or whether, after some level
of fast-acting resource penetration, the
capacity payment proves no longer
necessary.146
141 Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 17–18, ESA
May 2, 2011 Comments at 17 (citing NEPOOL
Markets Committee presentation, ‘‘Alternative
Technology Regulation Pilot Program.’’ November
9, 2010).
142 NEPOOL May 2, 2011 Comments at 6–7.
143 Duke May 2, 2011 Comments at 6.
144 NEPOOL May 2, 2011 Comments at 8, IRC
May 2, 2011 Comments at 5–6.
145 SoCal Edison May 2, 2011 Comments at 4–5.
146 PIO May 2, 2011 Comments at 10.
E:\FR\FM\31OCR2.SGM
31OCR2
67272
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 210 / Monday, October 31, 2011 / Rules and Regulations
srobinson on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
ii. Calculation of Opportunity Costs
92. Most commenters state their belief
that the RTO or ISO is in the best
position to calculate a resource’s
opportunity costs. ENBALA, IRC, ISO–
NE, NYISO, PIOs, PJM, and Xtreme
Power state that the RTO or ISO should
calculate cross-product opportunity cost
for inclusion in the capacity payment,
as the RTO or ISO has the best
information to determine a frequency
regulation resource’s opportunity
cost.147 PJM states that the RTO or ISO
is also in the best position to determine
inter-temporal opportunity costs and
should be allowed to calculate this as
well.148
93. ISO–NE contends that if the
resource owner were required to
calculate its own cross-product
opportunity costs, it would need to
build into that bid an ex ante risk
premium, to account for the possibility
of large swings in the locational
marginal price (LMP).149 NECPUC
shares ISO–NE’s concerns over the
possibility of ex ante determination of
opportunity costs and requests that the
Commission allow for flexibility to
address the undue discrimination
described in the NOPR.150
94. NEPOOL states that a proposal to
include cross-product opportunity costs
in the regulation clearing price was the
subject of much discussion during
original stakeholder consideration of the
regulation market re-design in ISO–NE.
At that time, according to NEPOOL, it
was concluded that determining
opportunity costs ex ante would be
significantly more complex than the
current ex post method and would
entail higher implementation costs.151
NEPOOL states that it has not explicitly
considered the inclusion of intertemporal opportunity costs, but it notes
that there is no restriction on including
these costs in a resource’s bid.
95. ELCON is the only commenter to
recommend that all opportunity costs be
market-based and calculated by the
supplier. ELCON states that the supplier
is in the best position to determine these
costs.152
96. ENBALA states that resources
should submit regulation offers that
reflect inter-temporal opportunity
costs.153 VCharge states that while it
does incur inter-temporal opportunity
147 ENBALA May 3, 2011 Comments at 8, IRC
May 2, 2011 Comments at 7, ISO–NE May 2, 2011
Comments at 2, PIOs May 2, 2011 Comments at P
13, Xtreme Power May 2, 2011 Comments at 6.
148 PJM May 2, 2011 Comments at 5.
149 ISO–NE May 2, 2011 Comments at 13–14.
150 NECPUC May 2, 2011 Comments at 3.
151 NEPOOL May 2, 2011 Comments at 7.
152 ELCON May 2, 2011 Comments at 4.
153 ENBALA May 3, 2011 Comments at 8.
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:29 Oct 28, 2011
Jkt 226001
costs, because it is a price-taker in the
ISO–NE market where it operates, it is
uncertain how the inclusion of this cost
will affect its operation.154
97. Powerex generally supports
inclusion of opportunity costs in the
market clearing price. However, it
argues that inter-temporal opportunity
costs may be complicated to implement
and lead to an uneconomic solution. In
addition, Powerex believes that intertemporal opportunity costs are
unnecessary. Powerex states that
resources that bid into a day-ahead
regulation market will typically know
its award by 1 p.m. prior to the delivery
day. As such, the resource will have at
least 11 hours to ensure its resource is
at the desired state by participating in
the wholesale energy market. Therefore,
Powerex suggests that inter-temporal
opportunity costs only be included in
bids for resources that are precluded
from participation in the wholesale
energy market.155 Powerex requests that
the Commission clarify how intertemporal opportunity costs will work in
practice.156
98. CAISO states that its current
market design allows a regulating
resource to earn the marginal resource’s
opportunity cost, including crossproduct opportunity costs. CAISO
asserts that while there is no formal
compensation mechanism for intertemporal opportunity costs, bidding
rules do not prevent scheduling
coordinators from including them in
supply bids. CAISO requests that the
Final Rule not preclude the use of such
informal compensation mechanisms to
account for inter-temporal opportunity
costs.157
c. Commission Determination
99. The Commission finds that paying
to all cleared frequency regulation
resources a uniform clearing price that
includes the marginal resource’s
opportunity costs is just and reasonable.
Accordingly, this Final Rule requires
that all RTOs and ISOs with centrallyprocured frequency regulation resources
must provide for such opportunity costs
in their tariffs. Further, this uniform
clearing price must be market-based,
derived from market-participant bids for
the provision of frequency regulation
capacity. As commenters recognize,
contrary market pricing rules would
consistently result in artificial and
inaccurate prices that do not include the
total cost of reserving regulation
capacity. In addition, paying an out-of154 VCharge
155 Powerex
156 Id.
at 5.
157 CAISO
PO 00000
April 27, 2011 Comments at 3.
May 2, 2011 Comments at 6–8.
May 2, 2011 Comments at 17–18.
Frm 00014
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
market unit-specific opportunity cost,
rather than a uniform clearing price, can
result in the market basing the
commitment of regulating units on bids
that do not reflect the true cost of
providing capacity, potentially leading
to committing units with higher costs
than other units not committed. By not
paying a uniform clearing price, it is
possible, for instance, to dispatch a unit
with relatively low explicit capacity
costs but very high opportunity costs,
rather than a lower-cost unit which has
relatively higher explicit capacity costs
but low opportunity costs. This can
result in distorted investment and entry
decisions by market participants. Paying
to all cleared frequency regulation
resources a uniform price that includes
opportunity costs will ensure that all
appropriate costs are considered and
will send an efficient price signal to
current and potential market
participants. This will also be consistent
with long-standing Commission policy
approving uniform clearing prices.158
100. We decline to specify, as
requested by Duke, certain
circumstances under which certain
resources should not receive the
capacity payment. Specifically, Duke
provides the example of an energy
storage resource, stating that it should
not be eligible for a capacity payment
during the time it charges in order to
attain a charge state that allows it to
provide frequency regulation service.
Duke’s example ignores the fact that a
storage resource that is charging could
be, at the same time, providing
frequency regulation service at the
direction of the system operator and
therefore is appropriately paid for the
capacity it sets aside to provide
frequency regulation service. We
recognize that some RTOs and ISOs
manage the charge state of energy
storage resources, while others do not.
We find that it is appropriate to allow
the RTOs and ISOs flexibility in
addressing this issue and explaining any
implications for compensation.
101. The Commission rejects PIOs’
argument that the capacity payment
should be wholly discontinued, in the
event that it proves no longer necessary.
158 See, e.g., PJM Interconnection, L.L.C., 117
FERC ¶ 61,331, at P 141 (2006); Commonwealth
Edison Company, 113 FERC ¶ 61,278, at P 43 (2005)
(citing New York Independent System Operator,
Inc., order on reh’g, 110 FERC ¶ 61,244, at P 65 n.76
(2005) (explaining that NYISO uses this method
because ‘‘under this model, the generator has the
proper incentive to bid the lowest price that covers
its marginal cost, knowing that if the market
produces a higher price it will receive the market
price’’)); and New England Power Pool, 85 FERC
¶ 61,379 (1998), reh’g denied, 95 FERC ¶ 61,478,
at 61,074 (2001) (approving market clearing prices
in energy and ancillary services markets).
E:\FR\FM\31OCR2.SGM
31OCR2
srobinson on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 210 / Monday, October 31, 2011 / Rules and Regulations
The capacity payment is necessary,
because it exists in order to ensure that
resources are indifferent between
offering their capacity as a frequency
regulation resource or as an energy
resource. While the market-clearing
price for frequency regulation service
may eventually fall as lower-cost
resources enter the market, the capacity
payment provides resources that clear as
frequency regulation capacity
recompense for holding such capacity in
reserve from the energy and other
markets so that it is available to the
system operator as frequency regulation
capacity.
102. Regarding cross-product
opportunity costs, which reflect the
foregone opportunity to participate in
the energy or ancillary services markets,
the Commission finds that it is
appropriate for the RTOs and ISOs to
calculate this and include it in each
resource’s offer to supply frequency
regulation capacity, for use when
determining the market clearing price
and which resources clear. Therefore we
will require this. We agree with PJM,
NYISO, IRC, and other commenters
which state that the RTOs and ISOs
have the necessary and accurate
information for determining this cost.
Further, ISO–NE and NEPOOL both
express concern that requiring a
resource to bid in its own cross-product
opportunity costs could result in
inefficient prices as resources include a
risk premium. We disagree with
ELCON’s argument that the resource is
in the best position to determine its
cross-product opportunity costs.
Because cross-product opportunity costs
are calculated based on the clearing
prices of other energy and ancillary
service products, specific knowledge of
the market variables used to formulate
these prices is necessary in order to
accurately calculate the opportunity
cost of providing frequency regulation
service. RTOs and ISOs have unique
access to this information and,
accordingly, RTOs and ISOs are in the
best position to perform accurate crossproduct opportunity cost calculations.
103. Regarding inter-temporal
opportunity costs, there is little
agreement on how these costs should be
calculated, and to whom that
responsibility should fall. The
Commission will require the RTOs and
ISOs to allow for inter-temporal
opportunity costs to be included in a
resource’s offer to sell frequency
regulation service, with the requirement
that the costs be verifiable. We find that
inter-temporal opportunity costs are a
legitimate cost for a market participant
to include in its offer to sell frequency
regulation and thus must be allowed.
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:29 Oct 28, 2011
Jkt 226001
However, we will allow the RTOs and
ISOs to propose who is responsible for
calculating such costs, whether the RTO
or ISO itself or market participants.
2. Payment for Performance
a. NOPR Proposal
104. The Commission preliminarily
found that requiring a component in the
frequency regulation compensation
mechanism that recognizes the
resource’s real-time provision of
frequency regulation service is
necessary to remedy undue
discrimination and ensure just and
reasonable rates in the organized
wholesale electricity markets.159 As
stated in the NOPR, resources that
provide more value to the grid by doing
more of the work to correct ACE
deviations, through the provision of
frequency regulation service, should be
paid more than resources doing less
work. Accordingly, taking performance
into consideration is a key element of
ensuring that any frequency regulation
compensation mechanism is just and
reasonable. The Commission, therefore,
proposed to require that all regulating
resources be paid for their performance,
for instance, with this payment taking
the form of a payment for each MWh,
up or down, provided by the resource in
response to the system operator’s
dispatch signal. Specifically, an RTO or
ISO would determine the total
movement up and down and then
multiply that sum by a price-per-MWh
of ACE correction. The NOPR solicited
comment on the proposed method and
whether there are alternative payments
for performance that address concern
about undue discrimination.160
105. The Commission also proposed
that the price-per-MWh of ACE
correction be market-based. Specifically,
resources would specify the capacity (in
MW) available to provide regulation, a
ramp rate (in MW/minute), and bid into
the market a price-per-MW ramping
capability or a price-per-MWh of ACE
correction. The RTO or ISO would then
determine the least cost set of resources
and set the price-per-MWh of ACE
correction based on the bid of the
marginal regulating resource. The
alternative to a market-based price is to
use an administratively set price-perMWh of ACE correction. The
Commission sought comment on this
proposal as well as the alternative of an
administratively determined price,
including how an administratively
determined price could be set.
159 NOPR,
160 Id.
PO 00000
134 FERC ¶ 61,124 at P 37.
P 37.
Frm 00015
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
67273
b. Comments
i. Market-Based Pricing Versus
Administratively-Determined Prices
106. Regarding whether the price used
to calculate the performance payment
should be market-based or
administratively-determined, the
majority of commenters who
commented on this topic expressed a
preference for a market-based option.161
They argue that market-based pricing
will encourage resources with the
lowest costs to provide regulation
movement to enter the market and
ensure that rate-payers receive the
benefit of new low-cost resources
competing in the market. According to
commenters, allowing the market to
establish the compensation for
resources’ performance will allow more
economically efficient outcomes and
create appropriate incentives for market
participants. Specifically, they contend,
a market-based price would encourage
resources to make bids that accurately
reflect their costs of ramping up and
down, and thus would ensure that
resources which can provide ramping
capability most cost-effectively will be
selected and, in turn, should lower costs
to customers.162
107. Powerex claims that use of a
forecast for ACE correction would allow
RTOs and ISOs to include the mileage
payment in their co-optimization and
determine an appropriate market
clearing price for the mileage
payment.163 PJM states that the
proposed dollars-per-MW bidding and
market-clearing mechanisms best
capture the market-based value of
ramping regulating units, and can be
efficiently and accurately modeled in
market-clearing algorithms. PJM
suggests that on-going updates to these
models will be required to ensure that
market results and compensation
correctly align with resource
performance.164
108. TAPS argues that to require that
performance payments for frequency
regulation service be administrativelydetermined would be especially
disruptive to region-specific market
designs and unwarranted. It argues that
it would not be in the public interest to
then require that prices in this market
segment be administratively161 Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 30, ESA
May 2, 2011 Comments at 29, EDF May 2, 2011
Comments at P 17, ELCON May 2, 2011 Comments
at 4, PJM May 2, 2011 Comments at 7, Powerex May
2, 2011 Comments at 8–9, SoCal Edison May 2,
2011 Comments at 10, TAPS May 2, 2011
Comments at 8, Xtreme Power May 2, 2011
Comments at 7.
162 Xtreme Power May 2, 2011 Comments at 7.
163 Powerex May 2, 2011 Comments at 8.
164 PJM May 2, 2011 Comments at 7.
E:\FR\FM\31OCR2.SGM
31OCR2
67274
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 210 / Monday, October 31, 2011 / Rules and Regulations
determined.165 TAPS notes that no
showing has been made, and there is no
reason to expect, that the maximum
necessary price to elicit frequency
response offers cannot be revealed
through a properly structured bid-based
market.166
109. Although supporting a marketbased price, Powerex argues that if the
Commission finds that an
administratively-set price is
appropriate, that price should be based
on the frequency regulation capacity
price, in order to provide transparency
and certainty for market participants.167
ii. Calculating the Performance Payment
and Bidding Parameters
110. Regarding the form a
performance payment should take,
Beacon and ESA both state that they
support a performance payment that
takes the form of a payment for each
MW, up or down, provided by the
resource in response to the system
operator’s dispatch signal multiplied by
a market-based price per MW-movement
based on the marginal unit’s cost to
ramp up and down.168 Beacon argues
that this would correspond to each
resource’s contribution to ACE
correction and is consistent with what
it views as industry best practices, i.e.
the current policy in ISO–NE.169 Beacon
cites data from its ISO–NE operation to
show that the mileage payment it
receives is approximately three times
that of an allowable slower-responding
resource, yet it actually does more than
three times the work.170
111. Beacon and ESA contend that a
payment to all resources based on their
MW movement, up and down, will
encourage all resources to offer as much
ramp-rate capability as possible because
the resource will be compensated for the
additional movement (and additional
costs it incurs) to provide this
service.171 Beacon and ESA further
argue that having bidding parameters
that match the way payments are
ultimately calculated will aid resources
in determining their bidding strategy.172
Beacon and ESA recommend that the
appropriate bidding parameters include
the total MW offered for frequency
regulation and the $/MW of ramping
capability. They contend that the cost
165 TAPS
May 2, 2011 Comments at 8.
at 9–10.
167 Powerex May 2, 2011 Comments at 9.
168 Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 19, ESA
May 2, 2011 Comments at 27–28.
169 Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 27.
170 Id. at 28.
171 Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 29, ESA
May 2, 2011 Comments at 28.
172 Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 29, ESA
May 2, 2011 Comments at 28.
srobinson on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
166 Id.
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:29 Oct 28, 2011
Jkt 226001
for ramping up and down in response to
an RTO or ISO control signal is the
increased fuel costs of operating in a
non-steady state condition, the
increased costs of operations and
maintenance due to additional ‘‘wear
and tear’’ on the equipment, and
potentially the cost of decreased cycle
life.173
112. CESA recommends that each
resource should bid in its price-per-MW
of movement for regulation service and
the system operator should set the priceper-MW used in the performance
payment at the price of the marginal
unit’s bid. While CESA notes that
another method for calculating the
performance payment would be to base
it on the total amount of MWh of ACE
correction, no matter the method used,
it is most important that the bidding
parameters match the way
compensation is calculated so that
resources can most easily determine
their bidding strategy.174
113. CAISO questions whether the
ISO’s bid optimization and ultimate
performance payment should reflect a
resource’s pre-certified ramping
capability or a resource’s actual
performance for which a resource would
receive a payment for moving in either
the up or down direction.175
114. OMS and VCharge ask the
Commission to clarify the need for both
a price-per-MWh ramping capability
and price-per-MW of ACE correction
parameters in a frequency regulation
service offer.176 OMS indicates that it is
not consistent to have both of these
pricing parameters in the ramping
portion of the frequency regulation
offer. OMS states that it interprets priceper-MWh as a parameter on which the
system operator would make dispatch
decisions, while price-per-MW of ACE
correction would be a parameter used
for determining the market-clearing
price for ramp. Once a clarification is
made, OMS requests further time to
comment on that clarification.177
115. ENBALA argues that
compensating resources based on a
price-per-MW of ACE correction bid is
not advisable. It argues that calculating
such a bid price would be difficult for
the resource, as would be verification of
the bid. It contends that settlement
would also be complex. ENBALA
recommends instead that resources
submit a price-per-MW ramping ability,
173 Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 30, ESA
May 2, 2011 Comments at 29.
174 CESA May 2, 2011 Comments at 9.
175 CAISO May 2, 2011 Comments at 19.
176 OMS May 2, 2011 Comments at 7, VCharge
May 2, 2011 Comments at 4 (citing the NOPR at P
37).
177 OMS May 2, 2011 Comments at 7–8.
PO 00000
Frm 00016
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
which would reflect the costs associated
with movement of the device, i.e.
variable O&M costs such as fuel
consumption and mechanical fatigue.178
116. Primus Power recommends that
compensation for performance be based
on the net energy contribution of a
resource. Primus Power defines this as
the total MWh delivered by the resource
in the direction of the control signal
minus the total MWh delivered against
the control signal (or delivered in excess
of the control signal). This would
determine the quantity for which the
frequency regulation service provided
would be compensated. To determine
the price, Primus Power proposes using
the market clearing price for frequency
regulation capacity as a basis.
Specifically, Primus Power recommends
multiplying the capacity price by some
weight, and then multiplying this by the
MWh the resource delivered over the
settlement period, as a fraction how
much an ‘‘ideal’’ resource would have
delivered.179
117. Regarding how resources would
bid their costs into such a market,
NEPOOL states that the ISO–NE
regulation market currently operates on
a system that minimizes total customer
payment, and it supports the continued
application of the current market
design.180
118. TAPS argues that a resource’s
offering price-per-MW of ACE
correction should be expected to
typically reflect only variable operating
costs for oscillating a resource’s output
instead of holding it steady. TAPS
provides an example to illustrate that
the resource’s offer price for frequency
regulation service ought to reflect the
amount of revenue that would make the
resource indifferent between being
dispatched up and down around its set
point over some period of time and
sitting constant at the set point. This
offer can be calculated by the
resource.181 In addition, TAPS notes
that bids for frequency regulation may
require mitigation in certain
circumstances. TAPS states that regional
market designs should provide for
mitigation, and the Commission should
defer to the regions to decide what
mitigation scheme would be
effective.182
119. SoCal Edison encourages the
Commission to consider both ex ante
and ex post calculation of market prices.
SoCal Edison states that an ex ante
approach will likely make it easier to
178 ENBALA
May 2, 2011 Comments at 8.
Power April 18, 2011 Comments at 6.
180 NEPOOL May 2, 2011 Comments at 9.
181 TAPS May 2, 2011 Comments 9–10.
182 Id. at 10.
179 Primus
E:\FR\FM\31OCR2.SGM
31OCR2
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 210 / Monday, October 31, 2011 / Rules and Regulations
establish a clearing price for the service,
whereas an ex post performance
payment ensures the market only pays
for what was delivered.183
120. Both ESA and Beacon
recommend that the Commission allow
the RTOs and ISOs to base their
compensation schemes on a single bid
if it so chooses; that is, as is done in
ISO–NE, one bid can be submitted
reflecting the costs of frequency
regulation capacity, and from this, the
payment for both capacity and
performance can be determined. Beacon
and ESA state that this has been used
successfully in ISO–NE, where the split
of compensation is administratively
determined in order for an ‘‘average’’
resource to receive half its
compensation from the capacity
payment and half from its performance
payment. Both ESA and Beacon state
that while this does not allow ISO–NE
to optimize in real-time like a two-bid
market would, it does send the correct
price signals to market participants.184
srobinson on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
iii. Creating a New Ancillary Service
Product
121. Various commenters suggest that
the Commission specifically define
faster- and slower-ramping resources, or
use speed to distinguish various
resources for purposes of calculating the
performance payment.
122. For example, Viridity and
Starwood/Premium recommend that
‘‘fast’’ and ‘‘slow’’ resources be treated
as different products or offering
different services.185 Viridity further
recommends that the Commission not
change how slow resources are
compensated for the provision of
frequency regulation service, i.e. make
no performance payment to slow
resources. However, Viridity would
have the Commission require that a
performance payment be made to fast
resources providing frequency
regulation service.
123. Viridity also suggests that the
performance payment made to fast
responding resources be based on the
price-per-MWh of ACE correction,
rather than a price-per-MW of ACE
correction.186
124. Manitoba Hydro asserts that
when regulation prices are marketbased, ancillary market design should
establish a clearing price that preserves
the value ratio between fast and slow
183 SoCal
Edison May 2, 2011 Comments at 10.
May 2, 2011 Comments at 31–33, ESA
May 2, 2011 Comments at 30–32.
185 Viridity May 2, 2011 Comments at 2.
186 More explanation can be found below in our
discussion of accuracy, where Viridity’s proposal
for an accuracy measure is discussed. Viridity May
2, 2011 Comments at 6.
184 Beacon
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:29 Oct 28, 2011
Jkt 226001
ramping resources. Manitoba Hydro
suggests that this could be
accomplished by establishing fast,
medium and slow regulation products,
and clearing the market with the
constraint that more valuable products
must clear at a higher price.187
125. CAISO argues that system
operators could define a fast-ramping
ancillary service product with a ramp
requirement based upon a change in
output over a period of time, such as
four seconds. It contends that System
operators would then use fast-ramping
resources as primary responders to
changes in ACE.
iv. Other Comments Regarding the
Performance Payment
126. SoCal Edison adds that after
market system design, each market will
have to be scrutinized for criteria such
as barriers to entry. If analyzing the new
system does not reveal workable
competition, then the Commission will
have to define market power mitigation
before letting such markets run.188
127. TAPS does allow that in some
necessary instances, regional market
designs should provide for mitigation,
and it may well be appropriate to
mitigate offers down to an
administratively-determined level
where the resource is indifferent
between providing frequency regulation
service (actual movement up and down)
and remaining steady at a given set
point.189
c. Commission Determination
i. Market-Based Pricing Versus
Administratively-Determined Prices
128. The Commission will require use
of a market-based price, rather than an
administratively-determined price, on
which to base the frequency regulation
performance payment. This price must
reflect the market participant bids
submitted by resources for the provision
of frequency regulation service. As
commenters note, a market-based price
for frequency regulation will encourage
market participants to accurately bid
their cost to provide the service. A
resource that chooses to increase its
offer price could find itself in a position
of not being dispatched and, therefore,
losing potential revenues. Additionally,
unlike an administratively-based price,
which could be subject to a potentially
lengthy stakeholder and/or adjudicative
process each time the price was
changed, a market-based price will
better reflect current system conditions
and need for frequency regulation,
187 Manitoba
Hydro May 2, 2011 Comments at 4.
Edison May 2, 2011 Comments at 10.
189 TAPS May 2, 2011 Comments 10.
188 SoCal
PO 00000
Frm 00017
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
67275
thereby providing market participants
with an efficient price signal.
129. Further, as PJM states, a marketbased price can be efficiently and
accurately modeled in the marketclearing algorithm. For these reasons,
we find it just and reasonable to require
that all RTOs and ISOs base their
payment for frequency regulation
service on a market-based price.
130. However, as described more fully
in the next section, unlike what was
proposed in the NOPR, we will not
require a specific methodology for how
that market-based price shall be
determined. We will not mandate
specific bidding parameters or other
technical details that will determine the
pricing methodology. We will require
two-part bidding; though we are
mindful that CAISO and ISO–NE each
noted the expected difficulty or ease
with which the proposed NOPR changes
can be integrated into existing market
solution software. ISO–NE’s concerns
about two-part bidding, in particular,
are addressed by the flexibility we will
allow in the bidding parameters that the
RTOs and ISOs may use and in that we
will not mandate a specific method by
which the RTOs and ISOs must specify
their market-clearing algorithms that
determine dispatch. The Commission
recognizes that two-part bidding
solutions are not insignificant
problems.190 However, they can be
overcome, and we believe the timeframe that we have required will allow
sufficient time to overcome such
hurdles. Beyond this, the Commission
will withhold judgment on the RTOs
and ISOs’ specific proposals until
receiving the compliance filings ordered
below. As TAPS states, market
participants have invested heavily in
market software and hardware, and the
different regional markets operate
slightly differently in how their markets
function. We conclude that mandating a
standardized solution on this issue
could result in significant costs and
disruption of existing stakeholder
processes. Therefore, we will allow the
RTOs and ISOs to determine how to
implement the market-based pricing we
are mandating, as discussed in the
compliance section below.
ii. Calculating the Performance Payment
and Bidding Parameters
131. Because RTO and ISO markets do
not all operate in the same manner, the
Commission will not mandate a
190 The problem of simple scoring rules used to
solve two-part bids is illustrated, for example, in
Swider, Derk J. ‘‘Efficient Scoring-Rule in Multipart
Procurement Auctions for Power System Reserve’’
IEEE Transactions on Power Systems, 22(4): 1717–
1725.
E:\FR\FM\31OCR2.SGM
31OCR2
srobinson on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
67276
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 210 / Monday, October 31, 2011 / Rules and Regulations
particular form that the performance
payment must take. Nor will we
mandate specific bidding parameters or
other technical specifications (including
requirements for qualification as a
regulation resource). Given regional
differences, we direct the RTOs and
ISOs to propose the specific technical
requirements that will meet the
requirements of this Final Rule. We will
require, however, that the clearing
performance price be paid uniformly to
all resources cleared during the same
settlement period, for the same reasons
discussed above. A uniform clearing
price sends an efficient price signal to
all current and potential market
participants. Further, paying a uniform
clearing price in this instance is
consistent with long-standing
Commission policy.191
132. While several commenters state
their preference for a particular method
for calculating the performance
payment, there is no compelling
evidence that one method will work
best in all RTOs and ISOs. As CESA
notes, there could be more than one
efficient way to compensate
performance; but resources should be
paid a uniform price for their frequency
regulation service.
133. In addition, we clarify that the
NOPR proposal was not intended to tie
the performance payment explicitly to a
resource’s ACE correction. The
performance payment proposed in the
NOPR was based on the amount of up
and down movement, in megawatts, the
resource provides in response to a
control signal.192 We recognize that, if
an RTO or ISO were to compensate a
resource based on how well it corrects
ACE, resources would have the
incentive to try to second-guess
dispatch signals in an effort to meet this
potentially contradictory goal. A
resource’s performance must be
measured based on the absolute amount
of regulation up and regulation down it
provides in response to the system
operator’s dispatch signal.
134. In response to SoCal Edison’s
argument that any performance payment
system should only pay for services
actually provided, the Commission
agrees and believes that measuring
accuracy, as is required below, will
account for this. In response to OMS
and VCharge, who question the need for
both a price-per-MWh ramping
capability and price-per-MW of ACE
correction, the Commission did not
191 See
supra n.153.
134 FERC ¶ 61,124 at P 34 and 37.
192 NOPR,
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:29 Oct 28, 2011
Jkt 226001
intend to state that there was a need for
both alternatives.193
iii. Creating a New Ancillary Service
Product
135. In response to Manitoba Hydro
and other comments, we do not believe
it is necessary to define faster- and
slower-ramping resources or use speed
to distinguish among resources to create
new ancillary services products based
on the ramping speed in the context of
this rulemaking. The purpose of this
Final Rule is to remedy undue
discrimination in compensation for the
existing frequency regulation service
employed by RTOs and ISOs by
ensuring that frequency regulation
resources are compensated based on
individual performance and ensure that
all eligible resources, not just traditional
resources and not just non-traditional
resources, providing frequency
regulation service within RTO or ISO
regulation markets are compensated at
the just and reasonable rate. While we
do not choose to require additional
categories of ancillary services based on
ramping speeds in the context of this
rulemaking, we do recognize that there
may be value in having a certain level
of granularity in defining the ancillary
service products. Most of the ancillary
services are defined by certain
characteristics, and we understand that
numerous different ancillary service
products could be created based on the
characteristics of different suppliers. We
understand that the RTOs and ISOs and
market monitors will continue
examining the ancillary service product
definitions and may propose to create
new ancillary services as market needs
evolve.194
iv. Other Comments Regarding the
Performance Payment
136. As to SoCal Edison’s and TAPS’s
concerns about the issue of market
power mitigation, we agree that there
may be circumstances under which an
RTO or ISO may wish to test for market
power and potentially impose
mitigation. We note that the
Commission has approved market
power mitigation in frequency
regulation markets.195 This rule requires
fundamental changes to the way RTOs
193 See 134 FERC ¶ 61,124 at P 38. The sentence
should have read ‘‘Specifically, resources would
specify the capacity (in MW) available to provide
regulation, a ramp rate (in MW/min), and bid into
the market a price-per-MWh ramping capability or
price-per-MW of ACE correction.’’
194 See, e.g., CAISO’s flexible ramping constraint,
available at https://www.caiso.com/informed/Pages/
StakeholderProcesses/
FlexibleRampingConstraint.aspx.
195 See PJM Interconnection, LLC, 125 FERC
¶ 61,231 (2008).
PO 00000
Frm 00018
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
and ISOs procure and compensate
frequency regulation resources, which
may render existing RTO and ISO
market power rules insufficient for
purposes of addressing market power
concerns. Given the Commission’s
recognition of the need for proper
mitigation methods in the current RTO
and ISO markets, we will require the
RTOs and ISOs either to submit tariff
provisions for market power mitigation
methods appropriate to redesigned
frequency regulation markets or to
explain how their current mitigation
methods are sufficient to address market
power concerns given the changes
required in this rulemaking.
3. Accuracy
a. NOPR Proposal
137. The Commission proposed that
the performance payment reflect the
resource’s accuracy in following the
system operator’s dispatch signal.
Specifically, the Commission proposed
that the accuracy be measured by the
RTO or ISO using currently available
telemetry technology. If an RTO or ISO
receives telemetry data every 10
seconds, for instance, it would be able
to measure over the course of 5 minutes
how often the resource was delivering
exactly the megawatts requested. The
resource would then be compensated for
the fraction of its mileage that met the
dispatch signal. This would provide a
disincentive to deviate from the
dispatch signal, which incorporates
actual ramping ability.
138. The Commission noted that there
was little agreement among the
technical conference panelists on how
accuracy should be incorporated into
the frequency regulation market design.
Therefore, the NOPR sought comments
on alternative methods, including
methods to incorporate accuracy into
the ACE correction calculation. The
Commission posited that it is possible to
approximate how a resource contributes
to correcting ACE by taking the
difference between the energy it
provides that was in the direction
needed to correct ACE at any moment
and the energy that was in the direction
opposite to what was needed to correct
ACE. Thus, a resource’s payment for
ACE correction could only include the
MWh that were actually correcting ACE.
The Commission sought comments on
how to structure payments for frequency
regulation that compensate a resource
for its contribution to ACE correction.
We sought comment on whether this
method could result in a resource being
penalized through lower mileage even
E:\FR\FM\31OCR2.SGM
31OCR2
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 210 / Monday, October 31, 2011 / Rules and Regulations
when it is following the system
operator’s dispatch signal.196
b. Comments
139. A number of commenters state
their support for some form of accuracy
adjustment for frequency regulation
service performance payments.197 Most,
however, are clear in their
recommendation that an accuracy
measure reflect how accurately a
resource follows the system operator’s
dispatch signal and not be based on any
measure of how the resource contributes
to ACE correction. Several also
emphasize the importance of allowing
RTOs and ISOs flexibility in how they
devise their own accuracy measures.
140. Beacon, CESA, and ESA state
that an accuracy metric will encourage
resources to accurately respond to the
control signal sent by the ISO and will
ensure that the performance payment is
truly tied to the resource’s actual service
provided.198 Beacon and ESA state that
the NYISO’s performance index is a
good example of an accuracy metric.
Beacon also states that, while NYISO
provides a good model, the 30 second
snapshot of accuracy is too slow to
capture the accuracy of a storage
resource that can dramatically change
its output each 6 second AGC cycle.
Therefore, Beacon recommends that any
accuracy metric be capable of measuring
performance each AGC dispatch cycle
and account for any latency in the ISO’s
dispatch software.199 Further, Beacon
and ESA warn that compensating a
resource for accuracy alone is not
sufficient to send efficient price signals.
They contend that the accuracy
adjustment must be tied to a
performance payment.200
141. ENBALA believes that a real-time
accuracy metric should be calculated by
the RTO or ISO to reflect how accurately
the regulation provided by a resource
follows the regulation requested. But
196 NOPR,
134 FERC ¶ 61,124 at P 40.
May 2, 2011 Comments at 2, Beacon
May 2, 2011 Comments at 38–39, CESA May 2,
2011 Comments at 11, ESA May 2, 2011 Comments
at 34–36, Duke May 2, 2011 Comments at 7, EDF
May 2, 2011 Comments at 21, ENBALA May 2, 2011
Comments at 3, IRC May 2, 2011 Comments at 3–
4, ISO–NE May 2, 2011 Comments at 6–8, NEPOOL
May 2, 2011 Comments at 10, Manitoba Hydro May
2, 2011 Comments at 3, NYISO May 2, 2011
Comments at 2 and 4–5, OMS May 2, 2011
Comments at 6–7, PJM May 2, 2011 Comments at
7–8, Powerex May 2, 2011 Comments at 9–10,
Primus Power May 2, 2011 Comments at 6, SoCal
Edison May 2, 2011 Comments at 2, Viridity May
2, 2011 Comments at 4–5, and Xtreme Power May
2, 2011 Comments at 7.
198 Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 38, CESA
May 2, 2011 Comments at 11, ESA May 2, 2011
Comments at 34.
199 Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 38.
200 Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 38, ESA
May 2, 2011 Comments at 35.
srobinson on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
197 Alcoa
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:29 Oct 28, 2011
Jkt 226001
ENBALA cautions that the accuracy
metric should take into account the time
needed to communicate data and the
frequency with which the dispatch
signal can change.201 Like ENBALA,
Manitoba Hydro supports an accuracy
measure provided that telemetry update
frequency and latency are adequately
considered.202
142. In response to the Commission’s
inquiry about whether a resource should
be compensated for performance when
it is moving in a direction that is against
ACE, Beacon, CESA, and ESA
recommend subtracting from the sum of
the resource’s total MW of up and down
movement any movement that is not in
the direction of correcting ACE. They
state that this could penalize a resource
even when it is following the system
operator’s dispatch signal, but that this
is appropriate because it further aligns
the payment the resource receives with
the value it provides to the grid.203 At
the same time, Beacon and ESA
acknowledge that a reward or penalty
structure should not change the
requirement that a resource follow the
operator’s dispatch signal.204
143. Duke agrees with the
Commission’s proposal that a resource’s
accuracy in following a dispatch signal
should be compensated through a
performance payment. However, Duke
does not agree with the proposal that a
resource be penalized if its MWh
contribution works against needed ACE
correction yet is compliant with the
system operator’s dispatch signal. Duke
cites the situation where a system
operator is dispatching resources, but
the dispatch signal is not designed just
to correct ACE.205
144. The IRC, ISO–NE, NEPOOL,
CAISO, PJM, MISO, NYISO, OMS, and
SoCal Edison recommend that the
accuracy metric should be designed to
provide an incentive to follow
operational instructions that facilitate
compliance with the system operator’s
dispatch signal, rather than focusing
narrowly on rewarding ACE correction
efforts.206 ISO–NE asserts that
compensation for accuracy should not
201 ENBALA
May 3, 2011 Comments at 3.
Hydro May 2, 2011 Comments at 3.
203 Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 39, CESA
May 2, 2011 Comments at 11, ESA May 2, 2011
Comments at 35–36.
204 Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 40, ESA
May 2, 2011 Comments at 36.
205 Duke May 2, 2011 Comments at 7.
206 IRC May 2, 2011 Comments at 3–4, ISO–NE
May 2, 2011 Comments at 6–8, NEPOOL May 2,
2011 Comments at 10, CAISO May 2, 2011
Comments at 12–14 and 18–19, PJM May 2, 2011
Comments at 7–8, MISO May 2, 2011 Comments at
7–8, NYISO May 2, 2011 Comments at 2, OMS May
2, 2011 Comments at 6–7, SoCal Edison May 2,
2011 Comments at 2.
202 Manitoba
PO 00000
Frm 00019
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
67277
be based solely on how well resource
output tracks ACE. It contends that this
creates an incentive for a resource
owner to ignore, or second-guess, an
ISO’s dispatch signal. ISO–NE explains
that central dispatch allows an ISO to
take advantage of its superior
information to produce a coordinated
AGC dispatch that produces the lowest
cost result. This dispatch may differ
from the outcome that would result
from resources individually chasing
after the expected ACE needs or
otherwise second-guessing the
operator’s dispatch signal. CAISO
suggests that paying for response to a
control signal rather than ACE
correction would be easier to
implement, avoids potential adverse
impacts to slow resources, and does not
tie compensation to one measure of
ACE.
145. At the same time, ISO–NE warns
that compensation not be based solely
on how closely a resource tracks its
AGC dispatch signal. ISO–NE imagines
a situation where frequency regulation
resources actually reduce their reported
ramping capability and offer in less
capacity in order to more easily follow
the dispatch signal. ISO–NE states that
this could defeat the entire purpose of
paying for performance.207 With this in
mind, ISO–NE recommends that the
Commission adopt a final rule that
provides the flexibility for accuracy
considerations to be incorporated into
the determination of frequency
regulation service eligible for
compensation, or into other measures of
regulation performance that may be
more appropriate for RTOs and ISOs in
different regions of the country.208 ISO–
NE also notes that measuring accuracy
is complex because it requires knowing
the realistic performance characteristics
of each resource and presumes reliable
instrumentation and dependable
communications.209 NEPOOL supports
retaining ISO–NE’s current method of
measuring performance.210
146. In addition, CAISO argues that
linking the performance payment to
ACE correction adds unnecessary
complexity to settlement of regulation
transactions.211 MISO also raises the
concern that the introduction of an
accuracy consideration to the
performance payment could require
substantial modifications to existing
207 ISO–NE
May 2, 2011 Comments at 6–7.
at 8.
209 Id. at 6.
210 NEPOOL May 2, 2011 Comments at 10.
211 CAISO May 2, 2011 Comments at 18–19.
208 Id.
E:\FR\FM\31OCR2.SGM
31OCR2
67278
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 210 / Monday, October 31, 2011 / Rules and Regulations
srobinson on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
RTO and ISO algorithms, and other
dispatch and accounting tools.212
147. OMS is concerned both about
technical issues, such as needed
telemetry, as well as, for example, a
situation where a resource is following
dispatch instructions, but those
dispatch instructions are contrary to
ACE. In that case, a resource following
the dispatch instruction should not be
penalized, OMS says.213
148. Primus Power and Viridity
generally support the Commission’s
proposal but offer their own versions of
how accuracy should be measured. As
describes above, Primus Power
recommends that ‘‘net energy
contribution’’ be the metric used to
determine performance payment. It
defines this as the total MWh delivered
by the resource in the direction of the
control signal minus the total MWh
delivered against the control signal (or
delivered in excess of the control
signal). Primus Power would use this as
the basis on which to base a resource’s
performance payment.214
149. Viridity recommends an
accuracy measure that can be broken
into three types of performance. A
resource that performs perfectly delivers
exactly the MWh as dispatched by the
system operator. This resource would
receive 100 percent of its performance
payment. A resource that does not
deliver the exact amount requested
through the dispatch signal, but which
nonetheless is delivering frequency
regulation service in the direction
requested would only receive a fraction
of its performance payment. Resources
that move in the opposite direction of
the dispatch signal will face a charge.
150. Viridity recommends that
accuracy be measured over what it
describes as a reasonable number of
intervals of the frequency regulation
signal. It cites 4 intervals, or every 16
seconds in the case of a 4 second
signal.215
c. Commission Determination
151. The Commission finds that
measuring and accounting for accuracy
in a resource’s compensation is just and
reasonable and will encourage resources
to report accurately their achievable
ramp rate and to follow the system
operator’s dispatch instructions. The
Commission also finds it appropriate to
base a resource’s accuracy on how well
it follows the dispatch signal and not on
its contribution to correcting ACE.
Indeed, we note that no commenters
212 MISO
May 2, 2011 Comments at 8.
May 2, 2011 Comments at 7.
214 Primus Power April 18, 2011 Comments at 6.
215 Viridity May 2, 2011 Comments at 4–5.
213 OMS
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:29 Oct 28, 2011
Jkt 226001
argue against accounting for frequency
regulation service providers’ accuracy.
152. First, as the RTOs and ISOs and
others note, the system operator does
not always use the AGC signal to correct
ACE to zero. There are situations where
a resource can be given an AGC signal
that is calibrated to anticipate changes
in ACE. Second, as noted above, to base
accuracy on ACE correction would be to
open the door to resources secondguessing dispatch signals and underreporting their actual ramping
capability. Neither of these would be a
desirable outcome. Indeed, a system
operator faced with a fleet of resources
with suddenly slower ramp rates would
be forced to procure more frequency
regulation capacity in order to be sure
of reliable operations. Further, the
system operator needs to have the
confidence that when a dispatch signal
is sent, resources will respond to it as
directed. This is best accomplished by
providing resources with an economic
incentive to follow dispatch signals.
153. Therefore, we will require all
RTOs and ISOs to account for frequency
regulation resources’ accuracy in
following the AGC dispatch signal when
determining the performance payment
compensation. However, we will not
mandate a certain method for how
accuracy is measured. For instance, we
will not, contrary to Beacon’s request,
mandate that the system operator
measure response on the same
frequency as the AGC signal (i.e., every
4 or 6 seconds). In combination with the
performance payment, accounting for
accuracy by tracking how closely a
resource follows its dispatch signal will
meet the goal of having compensation
reflect the work that frequency
regulation resources perform for the
system operator. We direct the RTOs
and ISOs to determine the technical
specifications of measuring accuracy.
We will not pre-judge the methods of
measuring accuracy presented by
Primus Power and Viridity. Any
stakeholder may use the standard RTO
and ISO stakeholder processes to
suggest how best to measure accuracy.
The RTOs and ISOs are in the best
position in the first instance to design
a method for measuring accuracy which
works with their system.
154. However, we will require the
RTOs and ISOs to use the same accuracy
measurement method for all resources.
That is, the RTO or ISO may not
develop an accuracy metric that applies
to one class of resources and another
accuracy metric that applies to other
resources. Doing so would move in the
direction of creating a ‘‘fast’’ and ‘‘slow’’
regulation service which we have
declined to do. The RTOs and ISOs will
PO 00000
Frm 00020
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
have flexibility in how the designed
method is used to determine accuracy
(e.g., the method could be used to define
an accuracy threshold or it could be
used to define a resource-specific
performance payment multiplier), but
all resources have to be measured on the
same basis. This flexibility will address
comments that we should allow RTOs
and ISOs to acknowledge the realistic
performance characteristics of the
resources providing frequency
regulation service.
4. Net Energy
a. NOPR Proposal
155. As explained in the NOPR,
currently, regulating resources receive a
payment (or charge) for the net energy
injected (or withdrawn) as a result of
providing regulation service in every
RTO and ISO market. The Commission
sought comment on the appropriateness
of retaining net energy payments in light
of the two-part payment proposed in the
NOPR.216 Specifically, the Commission
sought comment on whether the
provisions in existing tariffs for net
energy payments are redundant given
the proposed requirement discussed
herein that all RTOs and ISOs must pay
regulating resources a mileage payment
for the ACE correction service they
provide, or whether this payment is a
necessary, appropriate feature of dayahead and real-time energy account
balancing and settlement.
b. Comments
156. Many commenters support
retaining net energy balancing. ESA and
CESA state that hourly net-energy
payments and Performance Payments
are not redundant. ESA and CESA state
that both types of payments are needed
to ensure appropriate compensation of
frequency regulation providers.217
ENBALA agrees that net energy
payments in the existing tariffs should
be maintained.218 Occidental also
agreed, stating that net energy payments
must be maintained in order to (1)
recognize the true cost of frequency
regulation service, (2) avoid
subsidization of inefficient providers
and (3) avoid inefficient market
outcomes.219 Powerex suggests that the
Commission should require RTOs and
ISOs to continue to settle net energy in
each five-minute interval.220 Xtreme
Power reasons that frequency regulation
resources should be paid—or pay for—
216 NOPR,
134 FERC ¶ 61,124 at P 41.
May 2, 2011 Comments at 36, CESA May
2, 2011 Comments at 12.
218 ENBALA May 2, 2011 Comments at 10.
219 Occidental May 2, 2011 Comments at 4.
220 Powerex May 2, 2011 Comments at 10.
217 ESA
E:\FR\FM\31OCR2.SGM
31OCR2
srobinson on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 210 / Monday, October 31, 2011 / Rules and Regulations
the energy they inject or withdraw. It
argues that any net purchases of energy
should be charged to storage-based
frequency regulation providers at
wholesale rates.221 NEPOOL explained
that while mileage payments
compensate for what is done in the
regulation market; hourly net-energy
payments are part of the compensation
for what is done, and not done, in the
energy market.222 Primus Power
recommends retaining a separate
payment for net energy, stating that this
will ensure that capacity bids are not
distorted by the volatility in the realtime energy market.223
157. SoCal Edison states that there are
two fundamentally disparate ways to
treat net energy balancing. One is to
charge or credit a resource for its net
real-time energy and the other is to
exempt frequency regulation resources
from such crediting and charging.
Because, SoCal Edison states, the
specific market design impacts the final
outcome of using either method, it
recommends that the Commission not
mandate one particular method for
treating net energy balances.224
158. On the other hand, Manitoba
Hydro states that RTOs and ISOs should
eliminate net energy balancing.225 PIOs
recommend that the Commission not
allow what they view as a redundant
payment mechanism. Instead, PIOs
recommend that the Commission only
allow the retention of net energy
balancing and remuneration if the RTOs
and ISOs can show that this payment is
distinct from the service that will be
compensated under the NOPR’s
proposal, and that such payment is
necessary and not redundant.226
159. Beacon explains that tariffs that
require energy storage facilities to
purchase energy when providing
‘‘regulation down’’ without allowing for
a corresponding energy settlement
payment when the facility provides
‘‘regulation up’’ creates a financially
infeasible situation within which these
resources can operate. Tariffs that allow
energy storage to settle their energy on
a net basis will remove a significant
barrier to the participation of energy
storage projects connected at
transmission.227
160. ISO–NE suggests that net energy
payments not be mandated for storage
resources in the Final Rule, as, for
instance, expensive metering
221 Xtreme
Power May 2, 2011 Comments at 8.
May 2, 2011 Comments at 12.
223 Primus Power May 2, 2011 Comments at 7.
224 SoCal Edison May 2, 2011 Comments at 9.
225 Manitoba Hydro May 2, 2011 Comments at 4.
226 PIOs May 2, 2011 Comments at 9.
227 Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 40–41.
222 NEPOOL
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:29 Oct 28, 2011
Jkt 226001
requirements designed for generators
would preclude participation from a
number of promising technologies that
aggregate resources to provide
regulation. ISO–NE asserts that small
aggregated resources that take electric
service at the retail level and are
geographically dispersed should be
afforded the opportunity to provide
regulation without being required to
participate in the wholesale energy
market and meet the associated
requirements that could be costprohibitive for small resources.228 Other
ISOs, however, have not incorporated
net energy payments into their
regulation markets. PJM argues that
altering existing energy market
provisions will likely result in other
unintended consequences or will create
a disincentive to provide frequency
regulation service.229
c. Commission Determination
161. Upon consideration of the
comments received, the Commission
will take no action at this time on net
energy balancing as it is currently used
in the RTOs and ISOs; RTOs and ISOs
may retain their current rules in this
regard. Given the market rule changes
being required above, the Commission
currently does not find it necessary to
require that RTOs and ISOs change their
existing methods for netting injections
and withdrawals of energy over the
settlement period. In CAISO, for
instance, there is no relation between
the provision of frequency regulation
service and netting of energy. In other
markets, the treatment of net energy is
different. SoCal Edison makes the valid
point that the effect of the rules
governing treatment of net energy
balances depends on the specific market
design into which they are integrated.
As PIOs suggest, net energy balancing
can be an integral part of the RTOs’ and
ISOs’ accounting and system balancing
and we will impose no requirements
concerning this issue at this time.
162. Beacon states that a storage
resource that must pay the real-time
price when charging but is not likewise
credited when discharging that power in
response to a frequency regulation
signal is put in an untenable financial
position. We find that Beacon’s concern
is addressed by current RTO and ISO
rules. Frequency regulation resources
are charged at the real-time price for
energy withdrawals and credited for
energy injections.
228 ISO–NE
229 PJM
PO 00000
May 2, 2011 Comments at 14–15.
May 2, 2011 Comments at 9.
Frm 00021
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
67279
5. Technical Issues
a. Comments
163. Several commenters raise
concerns over a variety of technical
issues ranging from the definition of
ramp rate, to software issues, to the
substitutability of new technologies for
old.
164. On the issue of ramp rate, Alcoa
states that existing market designs are ill
suited for non-traditional resources, and
RTOs and ISOs tend to develop models
that force these resources to conform to
the traditional design rather than create
unique models. Alcoa refers to the
current clearing mechanism, which
multiplies a resource’s ramp rate by five
minutes. Alcoa argues that this design
limits its ability to provide demand
response, which is full range responsive
in one minute, to nearly one fourth of
its ramping capability. Alcoa claims that
this leads to inefficient utilization of
resources and increased costs.230
Similarly, SunEdison asserts that
limiting performance to a MW per
minute ramp response discriminates
against resources that can respond in
MW per second.231
165. Concerning software, CAISO
claims that implementation of the Final
Rule would present considerable
technical challenges. CAISO states that
in addition to creating new charge
codes, CAISO would have to develop a
settlement system based on more
granular telemetry than the current 10
minute settlement interval. According to
CAISO, at least 12 months would be
required to design, test and implement
the Commission’s proposed
performance payment mechanism. As
such, CAISO requests the Commission
provide a minimum of 18 months after
the issuance of the Final Rule to
implement necessary systems and
processes.232
166. Similarly, ISO–NE claims that
formulating a design that seeks to cooptimize energy, reserves, and
regulation, particularly where correctly
determining inter-temporal opportunity
costs for storage resources might require
an optimization horizon spanning hours
or days, is a daunting technical
challenge. It argues that formulating
such a design might require a complete
overhaul of existing real-time dispatch
algorithms.233
167. On the other hand, CESA states
that the Commission should ensure
implementation of the Final Rule is not
230 Alcoa
May 2, 2011 Comments at 5–6.
May 2, 2011 Comments at 2–4.
232 CAISO May 2, 2011 Comments at 20–22.
233 ISO–New England May 2, 2011 Comments at
9–13.
231 SunEdison
E:\FR\FM\31OCR2.SGM
31OCR2
67280
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 210 / Monday, October 31, 2011 / Rules and Regulations
srobinson on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
delayed by computer software. CESA
argues that there is no reason why the
compensation method as set forth in the
NOPR cannot be integrated into system
operators’ existing co-optimization
algorithms.234 Beacon and ESA argue
that while some flexibility may be
required, delaying the implementation
of the Final Rule would send
inappropriate price signals to investors
in energy storage technology that would
be detrimental to the industry.235
168. Raising concerns about technical
substitutability of resources, EEI asserts
that advantages in speed may be offset
by a non-traditional resource’s lack of
sustainability or automatic response.
EEI argues that pricing policies must
consider the needs of the entire system
including the proper mix of resources to
minimize system impacts. EEI theorizes
that excessive use of fast acting
resources may cause a balancing
authority to require more traditional
resources to offset the risk of being
shorted.236
169. Similarly, several commenters,
including SoCal Edison, ISO–NE,
CAREBS, and EPSA assert that overemphasis on faster regulation resources
without considering their ability to
provide sustained energy (for as long as,
for example, 15 minutes) may cause
overcorrection, decreased reliability,
and increased costs.237 CAREBS
suggests that the Commission should
consider how to compensate resources
that are both fast-ramping and longduration.238
170. Likewise, CAISO argues that a
fleet of resources that can respond
accurately to dispatch signals for an
appropriate duration is more valuable
than resources that can respond quickly.
CAISO therefore states that rules should
compensate resources that respond
accurately rather than simply
quickly.239
171. ENBALA further expresses a
concern that fast-responding resources
could cause reliability issues in the
power system by creating resonance
conditions with inter-area oscillations if
they respond to AGC signals with time
constants less than 10 seconds. It
explains that inter-area oscillations
occur as a result of an imbalance of
generation and system load. It argues
that, within an interconnection, some
generators will respond differently to
234 CESA
May 2, 2011 Comments at 10.
May 2, 2011 Comments at 36–37; ESA
May 2, 2011 Comments at 33–34.
236 EEI May 2, 2011 Comments at 8–9.
237 EPSA May 2, 2011 Comments at 6–7, SoCal
Edison May 2, 2011 Comments at 5–6, CAREBS
May 2, 2011 Comments at 6–8.
238 CAREBS May 2, 2011 Comments at 6–8.
239 CAISO May 2, 2011 Comments at 16.
235 Beacon
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:29 Oct 28, 2011
Jkt 226001
load changes depending on their
distance to the load center, which will
cause some units to speed up or down
more than others. As the generators
change their speed by a small amount
the power flow between the generators
will change. Once this imbalance
occurs, ENBALA contends, all
generators will continually move with
or against each other. When there is
insufficient or negative damping, the
oscillations will be sustained, or
increase, which ENBALA states can
cause damage to the power system.240
172. ENBALA argues that fast
responding resources should be
integrated in the regulation fleet, but it
states that the response times of
resources need to be maintained above
a safe level so as to eliminate this
reliability risk. It recommends that
NERC be allowed to assess the potential
reliability risk that AGC control action
within this time-frame represents before
the Commission accepts the proposed
incentive structure for frequency
regulation in the wholesale electricity
market.241
173. EnerNOC claims that the
Commission’s proposed telemetry
requirements represent a burden to
demand response participation by enduse customers. EnerNOC asserts that an
aggregated load management data
system can meet reporting requirements
without forcing each individual end-use
customer to conform to a system
operator’s normal telemetry
requirements. Accordingly, EnerNOC
encourages the Commission to allow for
flexible RTO or ISO telemetry
requirements for frequency regulation
services.242
174. Xtreme Power states that pilot
programs in several ISOs have identified
‘‘drift’’ in their frequency regulation
signal, whereby the amount of
regulation up does not equal the amount
of regulation down. Xtreme Power
asserts that ‘‘drift’’ interferes with the
ability of energy-limited resources to
provide regulation service, and suggests
that a net zero energy balance regulation
signal be implemented to address this
concern. In addition, Xtreme Power
questions whether RTOs and ISOs use
frequency regulation service to provide
other functions due to legacy control
practices, thereby placing an undue
burden on buyers and sellers of
regulation. Xtreme Power therefore
urges the Commission to require each
RTO and ISO report on the nature of
drift in their frequency regulation
markets, the causes of such drift, and
options to mitigate drift to allow for fair
competition between generators and
other resources.243
175. ENBALA also raises the issue of
what they term as an energy bias or lack
of energy neutrality in the frequency
regulation dispatch signal as a potential
barrier to entry for energy storage
devices and demand response.244
ENBALA describes a method by which
the signal could be split into two
different signals, one that is sent only to
energy-limited resources and that is
energy neutral, and another signal that
still contains the energy bias for other
resources.
176. Jack Ellis recommends an
examination of the costs, benefits, and
technical feasibility of an approach that
uses smaller market intervals and allows
providers of flexibility to update their
price/quantity offers more frequently
than is typically the case today.245 Mr.
Ellis claims that this is simply an
extension of intra-hour markets that
most RTOs and ISOs currently operate,
with two modifications. He contends
that the first is that the time intervals
will be shorter. Second, suppliers will
be able to revise their price/quantity
offers more frequently and closer to the
start of the market interval; a resource
would offer to sell or buy back a
quantity of energy in an upcoming 30
second, one minute or five minute
interval, rather than providing the grid
operator with a ramp rate well ahead of
time.246 Mr. Ellis states that this interval
could be, in theory, as short as the AGC
signaling interval, typically four or six
seconds, though market intervals of 30
seconds or one minute may be more
practical and equally effective.
b. Commission Determination
177. Regarding Alcoa’s concerns that
existing market designs are ill-suited for
non-traditional resources, we find, for
the reasons stated above, that a mileagebased performance payment component,
as required in this Final Rule, will
provide compensation that
appropriately recognizes a resource’s
actual ramp rate capability.
178. We reject SunEdison’s request to
redefine ramp rate. The expression of
ramp rates in MW per minute does not
limit the amount of capacity a resource
with faster response times may offer
into the frequency regulation market.
Redefining ramp rate in MW per second
would do no more than change the scale
by which ramp rates are reported.
243 Xtreme
Power May 2, 2011 Comments at 8–
10.
240 ENBALA
244 ENBALA
241 Id.
May 2, 2011 Comments at 6–7.
at 7.
242 EnerNOC May 2, 2011 Comments at 3.
245 Jack
PO 00000
Frm 00022
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
May 2, 2011 Comments at 4–6.
Ellis April 12, 2011 Comments at 4.
246 Id. at 4.
E:\FR\FM\31OCR2.SGM
31OCR2
srobinson on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 210 / Monday, October 31, 2011 / Rules and Regulations
179. In response to concerns that
faster-responding resources will result
in less sustainable or accurate resources
being procured for regulation service,
we disagree. This Final Rule only
modifies the way in which resources are
compensated for providing frequency
regulation. It does not address
requirements for qualification as a
resource eligible to participate in
wholesale regulation markets. Resources
that wish to provide frequency
regulation service must be capable of
sustained response for an appropriate
period as determined by the system
operator. Furthermore, linking the
performance payment to accuracy as
required in the Final Rule will provide
an appropriate incentive for resources of
any speed to accurately follow the
system operator’s control signal.
180. We agree with SoCal Edison’s
argument that each RTO or ISO should
be allowed to determine whether the
operator or the market participant is to
be responsible for managing energy
limitations. Nothing in this Final Rule
affects how RTOs and ISOs manage
energy limitations in their systems.
181. We further emphasize that
nothing in this Final Rule requires
payments for enhanced performance;
rather, it requires that resources
providing frequency regulation be paid
for the amount of service actually
provided. As to potential impacts from
over-reliance on faster-responding
resources, we note again that currently
the RTOs and ISOs meet their NERCrequired reliability standards. If an RTO
or ISO finds that the integration of too
much of one type of resource impacts its
ability to meet NERC reliability
standards, we expect that it will take the
necessary steps to ensure reliability.
182. As to comments seeking
compensation for resources that are both
fast-responding and long-duration, we
find that such resources will receive
appropriate compensation under the
Final Rule. In addition to receiving a
performance payment that rewards the
provision of frequency regulation
service, these resources will be
compensated for their long duration by
being able to offer their full regulation
capacity for a greater number of
regulation intervals.
183. In response to EnerNOC’s
statement regarding telemetry
requirements, we note that this Final
Rule directs no new telemetry
requirements. We also reiterate that
RTOs and ISOs are allowed flexibility in
complying with the Final Rule to
accommodate regional differences and
the needs of their particular region and
market, including telemetry
requirements.
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:29 Oct 28, 2011
Jkt 226001
184. We also reject as outside the
scope of this proceeding Xtreme Power’s
requests to require reporting on ‘‘drift’’
or energy neutrality in the frequency
regulation signal, as well as ENBALA’s
suggestion that RTOs and ISOs use
different frequency regulation signals
for different resources. These issues
concern a technical issue of dispatch,
not compensation. However, we note
that some RTOs and ISOs have
implemented changes to their markets
that serve to mitigate the impact of drift
on energy storage devices. For example,
MISO and NYISO have developed
market provisions that manage the
charge state of energy storage devices,247
while ISO–NE allows energy storage
devices to update their bids more
frequently.248 We encourage entities to
work together with stakeholders to
analyze potential impediments to new
technologies in all markets.
185. CAISO, ISO–NE, and CESA all
submit comments on the expected
difficulty or ease with which the
proposed NOPR changes can be
integrated into existing market solution
software. CAISO and ISO–NE request
that sufficient time be allowed for
implementation, with ISO–NE going so
far as to speculate that including intertemporal opportunity costs might be
infeasible and that two-part bidding
schemes can be very complex. As a
general matter, the Commission believes
that the deadlines discussed in the
compliance section below will allow
sufficient time for all RTOs and ISOs to
comply. First, we note that we are not
requiring RTOs and ISOs to be
responsible for calculating intertemporal opportunity costs; though we
do require that resources be able to
include such verifiable costs in their
bids. We agree with ISO–NE that the
decision of who should calculate intertemporal opportunity costs is best left to
the RTOs and ISOs. Requiring the RTO
or ISO to calculate this cost might
burden the system operator too much; in
other RTOs and ISOs, the system
operator might find it easier to complete
this task. Thus, we leave it to the
individual RTOs and ISOs, in the first
instance, to find the solution that best
fits their needs. Second, with regard to
ISO–NE’s concerns about two-part
bidding, while we do require two-part
bidding, we have not specified the
specific technical aspects of how those
bids are then used in the marketclearing algorithm. The Commission
247 See MISO, Energy and Operating Reserve
Markets Business Practice Manual, Attachment D,
Section 3.26; NYISO, Ancillary Services Manual,
Section 4.3.2.
248 See ISO–NE, Market Rule 1, Appendix J.
PO 00000
Frm 00023
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
67281
recognizes that two-part bidding
solutions are not insignificant problems
that might need to be addressed.249
However, we believe the time-frame set
forth herein for submitting compliance
filings will allow sufficient time to
overcome such hurdles.
6. Definition of Frequency Regulation
a. Comments
186. Duke seeks clarification of the
definition of ‘‘frequency regulation,’’
which Duke asserts is defined
differently in the NOPR than in the
NERC Glossary of Terms. It points out
that NERC’s definition includes both
‘‘primary frequency control’’ (i.e.,
turbine governor response) and
‘‘secondary frequency control’’ (i.e.,
AGC). In Duke’s view, the NOPR was
not clear as to whether both primary
and secondary frequency controls are
included, although Duke contends that
the body of the NOPR suggests that only
secondary frequency control is
included. Duke asks the Commission to
clarify this point or, in the alternative,
to direct NERC and its stakeholders to
examine the issue and propose a
resolution.250
187. ISO–NE expresses concern that
the NOPR defined frequency regulation
too narrowly by focusing exclusively on
responding to ACE to the exclusion of
broader reliability criteria. It proposes a
modified definition of frequency
response that considers that the
objective of the regulation market is to
provide a means for the balancing
authority to competitively procure
sufficient frequency regulation
resources to ensure compliance with the
NERC CPS1 and CPS2 standards.251
188. MISO argues that the
Commission’s proposed definition of
frequency regulation is inconsistent
with the Commission-approved NERC
definition. MISO contends that the
proposed definition characterizes
frequency regulation as a response to
transmission system ACE, while
frequency response is separated and
defined as an autonomous response by
generators to system frequency. MISO
claims that NERC’s definition, in
contrast, refers to a system’s ability to
maintain scheduled frequency, and
includes both AGC and governor
response. MISO argues that there is not
a direct correlation between scheduled
frequency and ACE. Furthermore, MISO
asserts that NERC’s definition appears to
encompass both frequency regulation
and frequency response as defined by
249 See
supra note 190.
May 2, 2011 Comments at 3–4.
251 ISO–New England May 2, 2011 Comments at
5–6.
250 Duke
E:\FR\FM\31OCR2.SGM
31OCR2
67282
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 210 / Monday, October 31, 2011 / Rules and Regulations
srobinson on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
the Commission. Accordingly, MISO
requests that the Commission reconsider
the proposed definition of frequency
regulation to avoid potential confusion
as a result of conflicting terms, or
limiting the flexibility of the system
operator to call on regulating resources
to maintain system balance and
reliability.252
189. In addition, Invenergy requests
that the Commission create standard
definitions and terminology for
regulation, with the intention of
avoiding confusion, inconsistency, and/
or the creation of redundant or
extraneous regulation products.253
190. IRC is also concerned that the
proposed definition of frequency
regulation in the NOPR is focused solely
on ACE, which IRC argues is only one
component of regulation service. Instead
of rapid response, IRC advocates for
‘‘smart response,’’ which it describes as
aligning the response characteristics of
all available resources with system
needs to provide the most efficient
means of managing frequency regulation
in each balancing authority Area. IRC
notes that a resource with rapid
response capability can provide
significant response to the ACE (i.e.,
following the ACE both up and down).
But IRC argues that a significant part of
that response may be unnecessary if the
response was strictly utilized for a zeroaveraging ACE. Alternatively, IRC
explains that the response could
provide significant value if it is directed
against a non-zero averaging ACE,
because in that case it would be utilized
against the overall system needs rather
than to merely ‘‘chase’’ ACE, which, as
only one part of the operational
equation, does not produce the most
effective operational response.254
b. Commission Determination
191. The Commission disagrees with
Duke’s contention that the NOPR is not
clear as to whether its definition of
frequency regulation includes both
primary and secondary frequency
controls. The NOPR stated, ‘‘Frequency
regulation service is the injection or
withdrawal of real power by facilities
capable of responding appropriately to a
transmission system’s frequency
deviations or interchange power
imbalance, both measured by the ACE
* * *. Frequency regulation is
distinguishable from Frequency
response.’’ 255
192. In response to ISO–NE., MISO,
and the IRC’s concerns that the
252 MISO
May 2, 2011 Comments at 3–5.
May 2, 2011 Comments at 3.
254 IRC May 2, 2011 Comments at 4–5.
255 NOPR, 134 FERC ¶ 61,124 at P 4–5.
253 Invenergy
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:29 Oct 28, 2011
Jkt 226001
Commission’s proposed definition of
frequency regulation in the NOPR is too
narrow and is inconsistent with the
Commission-approved NERC definition,
we address this issue in section 3 infra
by requiring that accuracy be measured
in relation to the system operator’s
dispatch signal and by revisions to the
proposed regulatory text. As described
below, we have revised the regulatory
text to define frequency regulation as
‘‘the capability to inject or withdraw
real power by resources capable of
responding appropriately to a system
operator’s automatic generation control
signal in order to correct for actual or
expected Area Control Error needs.’’ We
also address Invenergy’s request for a
standard definition. The alteration to
the proposed regulatory text, we believe,
provides a sufficiently detailed
definition of frequency regulation to
avoid confusion. The definition avoids
the implication that a system operator’s
dispatch signal for frequency regulation
resources always aims to drive ACE to
zero at any given moment in time, but
also describes only secondary frequency
control and does not include primary
frequency control, i.e., frequency
response. Further, the Commission finds
that the distinction between the pro
forma OATT and this new language will
not cause confusion because it applies
only to the organized wholesale
markets: the RTOs and ISOs.
7. Miscellaneous Issues
a. Comments
193. Several commenters discussed
various issues pertaining to barriers to
participation 256 and separating
regulation up and regulation down,257
and, a few commenters argue that the
Commission should adopt various
256 For
example, Powerex argues that restricting
units eligible to provide regulation service to units
within the RTO or ISO market footprint undermines
market liquidity and discourages the development
of competitive regulation markets. Accordingly,
Powerex requests that the Commission clarify that
RTOs and ISOs cannot unduly restrict participation
by external resources and must justify restrictions
solely on reliability or deliverability concerns.
Powerex May 2, 2011 Comments at 5–6. Occidental
requests that the Commission revise the definition
of demand response to state that an increase in load
in response to dispatch is also considered demand
response. Occidental May 2, 2011 Comments at
3–4.
257 Alcoa, AWEA, Occidental and Steel Producers
argue that the Commission should urge or require
separate regulation up and regulation down markets
in order to recognize the separate value of each
service and to promote more efficient regulation
response. Alcoa May 2, 2011 Comments at 7–8;
AWEA May 2, 2011 Comments at 4–5; Occidental
May 2, 2011 Comments at 1; Steel Producers May
2, 2011 Comments at 2.
PO 00000
Frm 00024
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
requirements related to NERC,258 or
storage facilities.259
b. Commission Determination
194. These issues are beyond the
scope of this proceeding, which is
limited to remedying the existing undue
discrimination in the compensation of
frequency regulation service in the
organized wholesale electricity markets.
This Final Rule is also not focused on
any particular resource type, but rather
is resource-neutral. The directives of
this Final Rule will ensure that all
eligible resources providing frequency
regulation service within existing RTO
or ISO frequency regulation markets are
compensated at the just and reasonable
rate.
195. We further emphasize that the
directives of this Final Rule apply only
to secondary frequency regulation in the
organized wholesale electricity markets
and not to primary frequency response.
As noted in the NOPR, the Commission
has separately released for public
comment a staff study evaluating the
use of frequency response metrics as a
tool to assess the reliability impacts of
varying resource mixes on the
transmission grid.260 However we
disagree with commenters who argue
that requiring the reforms directed
herein to ensure just and reasonable
rates will provide excessive
compensation in the secondary
frequency regulation markets. We
decline to impose generic requirements
in this Final Rule relating to
compensation reforms for other critical
ancillary services.
196. With respect to Starwood/
Premium’s request that the Commission
address in this proceeding the storagerelated issues raised in the Storage RFC
the Commission notes that, on June 16,
2011, the Commission issued a Notice of
258 EEI and Detroit Edison seek a requirement that
RTOs and ISOs develop pilot programs in
consultation with NERC to evaluate the impact of
non-traditional resources; Alcoa argues that NERC
performance standards are designed based on
traditional technologies and request that the
Commission direct NERC to study the reduction in
system requirements through integration of
nontraditional resources outside the scope of this
rulemaking; Duke states that it is unaware of any
technical study or NERC standard or requirement
that would indicate that a faster response to AGC
is necessary for reliable system operations and that
RTOs and ISOs are ultimately responsible for
determining what resources are necessary to
comply with the NERC reliability standards.
259 Starwood/Premium recommends that the
Commission consider adapting the NOPR proposal
to include storage devices that are able to provide
multiple services as discussed in the Commission’s
June 11, 2010 Notice of Request for Comments. See
Request for Comments Regarding Rates, Accounting
and Financial Reporting for New Electric Storage
Technologies, Docket No. AD10–13–000 (2010)
(Storage RFC).
260 NOPR, 134 FERC ¶ 61,124 at n.610.
E:\FR\FM\31OCR2.SGM
31OCR2
67283
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 210 / Monday, October 31, 2011 / Rules and Regulations
Inquiry that continues our examination
of storage-related issues.261 Because
these issues are being addressed in
another proceeding, we decline to
address them here.
III. Compliance Requirements and
Summary of Commission
Determinations and Findings
197. In this Final Rule the
Commission finds that current methods
for compensating resources for the
provision of frequency regulation are
unduly discriminatory. To remedy this
undue discrimination, the Commission
finds that it is just and reasonable to
require all RTOs and ISOs to modify
their tariffs to provide for a two-part
payment to frequency regulation
resources.
198. The first part of this payment
will be a capacity, or option, payment
for keeping a resource’s capacity in
reserve in the event that it is needed to
provide real-time frequency regulation
service. This payment must be a
uniform payment to all cleared
resources, and must be a payment that
includes the marginal unit’s opportunity
costs. The RTO or ISO must calculate
and include in its market-clearing
process the cross-product opportunity
costs of each resource offering its
capacity. We will leave to the RTOs and
ISOs the discretion of proposing to
whom the responsibility falls of
calculating any applicable intertemporal opportunity costs. This
capacity payment also must be based on
competitive market-based bids for the
provision of frequency regulation
capacity submitted by resources.
199. The second part of the payment
shall be a performance payment that
reflects the amount of work each
resource performs in real-time. This
payment must reflect the accuracy with
which each resource responds to the
system operator’s dispatch signal. The
performance payment must be marketbased (i.e., based on resource bids that
reflect the cost of providing the service).
We leave to the RTOs and ISOs to
propose such details as bidding
parameters and other details that may
need to vary by market and region.
200. Regarding accuracy, the
Commission finds that it is appropriate
to tie the measurement of a resource’s
accuracy to the system operator’s AGC
dispatch signal and not to ACE
correction. Therefore, each RTO and
ISO must propose a method for
measuring a frequency regulation
resource’s accuracy with respect to the
dispatch signal it is sent and reflecting
that accuracy in the resource’s payment.
We do require that the same accuracy
metric must be used for all resources
providing frequency regulation service
in an RTO or ISO.
201. The Commission recognizes that
making these changes could require
significant work on the part of the RTOs
and ISOs. Therefore, the tariff changes
needed to implement the compensation
approach required in this Final Rule,
including a uniform price for regulation
capacity, and a performance payment
for the provision of frequency regulation
service, with such payment reflecting a
resource’s accuracy in following the
AGC dispatch signal, must be filed
within 120 days of the effective date of
this Final Rule. We will allow further
180 days from that date for
implementation.
IV. Information Collection Statement
202. The Office of Management and
Budget’s (OMB) regulations require
approval of certain information
collection requirements imposed by
agency rules. Upon approval of a
collection(s) of information, OMB will
assign an OMB control number and an
expiration date. Respondents subject to
the filing requirements of a rule will not
be penalized for failing to respond to
these collections of information unless
the collections of information display a
valid OMB control number.
203. This Final Rule amends the
Commission’s regulations under Part 35
to require RTOs and ISOs to pay both
a uniform clearing price for frequency
regulation capacity to all cleared
frequency regulation resources and a
performance payment for the provision
of frequency regulation service, with the
latter payment reflecting a resource’s
accuracy of performance. To accomplish
this, the Commission requires RTOs and
ISOs to adopt tariff revisions reflecting
these changes. In addition to making
tariff changes, the Commission also
expects that RTOs and ISOs will be
required to modify existing software
systems. The information provided for
under Part 35 is identified as FERC–516.
204. Under section 3507(d) of the
Paperwork Reduction Act of 1995,262
the reporting requirements in this
rulemaking will be submitted to OMB
for review. In their notice of March 15,
2011, OMB took no action on the NOPR,
instead deferring their approval until
review of the Final Rule.
205. The Commission solicited
comments on the need for this
information, whether the information
will have practical utility, the accuracy
of provided burden estimates, ways to
enhance the quality, utility, and clarity
of the information to be collected, and
any suggested methods for minimizing
the respondent’s burden, including the
use of automated information
techniques. The Commission did not
receive any specific comments regarding
its burden estimates. The Public
reporting burden for the requirements
contained in the Final Rule is as
follows:
Data collection
Number of
respondents 263
Number of
responses
Hours per
response
Total hours
in year one
FERC 516
[1]
[2]
[3]
[1 × 2 × 3]
srobinson on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
Conforming tariff changes made by RTOs/ISOs (18 CFR 35.28(g)(3)). One
time burden.
Software changes made by RTOs/ISOs. One time burden264 ..........................
Totals ..........................................................................................................
261 Third-Party Provision of Ancillary Services;
Accounting and Financial Reporting for New
Electric Storage Technology, 135 FERC ¶ 61,240
(2011).
262 44 U.S.C. 3507(d).
263 SPP is not included in the respondents
because they currently do not have a frequency
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:29 Oct 28, 2011
Jkt 226001
5
1
100
5
........................
1
........................
1000
........................
regulation compensation mechanism in their tariff
and independent of this proceeding they have
indicated that they are already planning to
implement such a mechanism. Therefore, it is
expected that any additional burden on SPP due to
this proceeding will be de minimus.
PO 00000
Frm 00025
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
500.
5000.
5500 one
time burden.
264 This category was not included in the NOPR
estimates. Since issuing the NOPR the Commission
has determined that each RTO’s and ISO’s market
software will need to be modified in order to
comply with this final rule.
E:\FR\FM\31OCR2.SGM
31OCR2
srobinson on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
67284
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 210 / Monday, October 31, 2011 / Rules and Regulations
The additional one-time burden of
5,500 hours is being spread over the
next three years for the purposes of
submittal to the OMB, giving an average
additional annual burden of 1833 hours
(rounded) or 367 hours (rounded) per
year per respondent.
Cost to Comply: The Commission has
projected the cost of compliance to be
$687,500.
Total Annual Hours for Collection in
initial year (5500 hours) @ $125 an hour
[average cost of attorney ($200 per
hour), consultant ($150), technical
($125),265 and administrative support
($25)] = $687,500.
Title: FERC–516, Electric Rate
Schedules and Tariff Filings.
Action: Proposed Collection.
OMB Control No. 1902–0096.
Respondents for this Rulemaking:
Businesses or other for profit and/or
not-for-profit institutions.
Frequency of Information: As
indicated in the table.
Necessity of Information: The Federal
Energy Regulatory Commission is
requiring ISOs and RTOs to change their
tariffs to provide for compensation for
frequency regulation service in a
manner that remedies undue
discrimination in the procurement of
such service in the organized wholesale
electricity markets, and ensure just and
reasonable rates.
Internal Review: The Commission has
reviewed the proposed changes and has
determined that the changes are
necessary. These requirements conform
to the Commission’s need for efficient
information collection, communication,
and management within the energy
industry. The Commission has assured
itself, by means of internal review, that
there is specific, objective support for
the burden estimates associated with the
information collection requirements.
206. Interested persons may obtain
information on this information
collection by contacting the following:
Federal Energy Regulatory Commission,
888 First Street, NE., Washington, DC
20426, Attention: Ellen Brown, Office of
the Executive Director, email:
DataClearance@ferc.gov, phone: (202)
502–8663, or fax: (202) 273–0873.
207. Comments concerning this
information collection can be sent to the
Office of Management and Budget,
Office of Information and Regulatory
Affairs, Washington, DC 20503
[Attention: Desk Officer for the Federal
Energy Regulatory Commission, phone:
(202) 395–4718, fax: (202) 395–7285].
265 The Commission has increased this estimate
from $80/hour to $125/hour to account for the
software changes that will be needed to be done by
high level staff.
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:29 Oct 28, 2011
Jkt 226001
V. Environmental Analysis
208. The Commission is required to
prepare an Environmental Assessment
or an Environmental Impact Statement
for any action that may have a
significant adverse effect on the human
environment.266 The Commission
concludes that neither an
Environmental Assessment nor an
Environmental Impact Statement is
required for this Final Rule under
section 380.4(a)(15) of the Commission’s
regulations, which provides a
categorical exemption for actions under
sections 205 and 206 of the FPA relating
to the filing of schedules containing all
rates and charges for the transmission or
sale subject to the Commission’s
jurisdiction, plus the classification,
practices, contracts, and regulations that
affect rates, charges, classifications, and
services.222
VI. Regulatory Flexibility Act
209. The Regulatory Flexibility Act of
1980 (RFA) 267 generally requires a
description and analysis of final rules
that will have significant economic
impact on a substantial number of small
entities. The RFA mandates
consideration of regulatory alternatives
that accomplish the stated objectives of
a proposed rule and that minimize any
significant economic impact on a
substantial number of small entities.
The Small Business Administration’s
(SBA) Office of Size Standards develops
the numerical definition of a small
business.268 The SBA has established a
size standard for electric utilities,
stating that a firm is small if, including
its affiliates, it is primarily engaged in
the transmission, generation and/or
distribution of electric energy for sale
and its total electric output for the
preceding twelve months did not exceed
four million megawatt hours.269 Only
five ISOs and RTOs, not small entities,
are impacted directly by this rule.
210. CAISO is a non-profit
organization with over 54,000
megawatts of capacity and over 25,000
circuit miles of power lines. CAISO’s
annual total energy deliveries in 2009
were 230,754,000 MWh.
211. NYISO is a non-profit
organization that oversees wholesale
electricity markets, dispatches over 500
generators, and manages a nearly
11,000-mile network of high-voltage
lines. NYISO’s 2009 energy deliveries,
266 Regulations Implementing the National
Environmental Policy Act, Order No. 486, 52 FR
47897 (Dec. 17, 1987), FERC Stats. & Regs.,
Regulations Preambles 1986–1990 ¶ 30,783 (1987).
267 5 U.S.C. 601–12.
268 13 CFR 121.101.
269 13 CFR 121.201, Sector 22, Utilities & n.1.
PO 00000
Frm 00026
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
including transmission and distribution
losses and excluding station power was
680,767,000 MWh.
212. PJM comprises more than 600
members including power generators,
transmission owners, electricity
distributors, power marketers, and large
industrial customers, serving 13 states
and the District of Columbia. PJM’s net
energy for load in 2009 was 680,767,000
MWh.
213. MISO is a non-profit organization
with over 145,000 megawatts of
installed generation. MISO has over
57,000 miles of transmission lines and
serves 13 states and one Canadian
province. MISO’s annual transmission
billings for 2010 were 629,000,000
MWh.
214. ISO–NE is a regional
transmission organization serving six
states in New England. The system
comprises more than 8,000 miles of
high-voltage transmission lines and over
350 generators. In 2009, ISO–NE’s net
energy for load was 126,839,000 MWh.
215. Based on the above, the
Commission certifies this rule will not
have a significant economic impact on
a substantial number of small entities,
and therefore no regulatory flexibility
analysis is required.
VII. Document Availability
216. In addition to publishing the full
text of this document in the Federal
Register, the Commission provides all
interested persons an opportunity to
view and/or print the contents of this
document via the Internet through the
Commission’s Home Page (https://
www.ferc.gov) and in the Commission’s
Public Reference Room during normal
business hours (8:30 a.m. to 5 p.m.
Eastern time) at 888 First Street, NE.,
Room 2A, Washington, DC 20426.
217. From the Commission’s Home
Page on the Internet, this information is
available on eLibrary. The full text of
this document is available on eLibrary
in PDF and Microsoft Word format for
viewing, printing, and/or downloading.
To access this document in eLibrary,
type the docket number excluding the
last three digits of this document in the
docket number field.
218. User assistance is available for
eLibrary and the Commission’s Web site
during normal business hours from
FERC Online Support at (202) 502–6652
(toll free at 1–(866) 208–3676) or email
at ferconlinesupport@ferc.gov, or the
Public Reference Room at (202) 502–
8371, TTY (202) 502–8659. Email the
Public Reference Room at
public.referenceroom@ferc.gov.
E:\FR\FM\31OCR2.SGM
31OCR2
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 210 / Monday, October 31, 2011 / Rules and Regulations
VIII. Effective Date and Congressional
Notification
219. This Final Rule will become
effective on December 30, 2011. The
Commission has determined, with the
concurrence of the Administrator of the
Office of Information and Regulatory
Affairs, Office of Management and
Budget, that this rule is not a ‘‘major
rule’’ as defined in section 351 of the
Small Business Regulatory Enforcement
Fairness Act of 1996.
By the Commission. Commissioner Spitzer
is not participating.
Nathaniel J. Davis, Sr.,
Deputy Secretary.
In consideration of the foregoing, the
Commission amends Part 35, Chapter I,
Title 18 of the Code of Federal
Regulations as follows:
PART 35—FILING OF RATE
SCHEDULES AND TARIFFS
1. The authority citation for Part 35
continues to read as follows:
Authority: 16 U.S.C. 791a–825r, 2601–
2645; 31 U.S.C. 9701; 42 U.S.C. 7101–7352.
2. Amend § 35.2 by adding a new
paragraph (g) to read as follows:
■
Definitions.
*
*
*
*
*
(g) Frequency regulation. The term
frequency regulation as used in this part
will mean the capability to inject or
withdraw real power by resources
capable of responding appropriately to a
system operator’s automatic generation
control signal in order to correct for
actual or expected Area Control Error
needs.
3. Amend § 35.28 by adding a new
paragraph (g)(7) to read as follows:
srobinson on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with RULES2
■
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:29 Oct 28, 2011
Jkt 226001
*
*
*
*
*
(g) * * *
(7) Frequency regulation
compensation in ancillary services
markets. Each Commission-approved
independent system operator or regional
transmission organization that has a
tariff that provides for the compensation
for frequency regulation service must
provide such compensation based on
the actual service provided, including a
capacity payment that includes the
marginal unit’s opportunity costs and a
payment for performance that reflects
the quantity of frequency regulation
service provided by a resource when the
resource is accurately following the
dispatch signal.
Note: The following appendix will not
appear in the Code of Federal Regulations.
Appendix
■
§ 35.2
§ 35.28 Non-discriminatory open access
transmission tariff.
List of Commenters
A123 Systems, Inc. (A123)
Alcoa Inc. (Alcoa)
Alliance for Industrial Efficiency, Inc. (The
Alliance)
American Wind Energy Association (AWEA)
Beacon Power Corporation (Beacon)
California Independent System Operator
Corporation (CAISO)
California Energy Storage Alliance (CESA)
Coalition to Advance Renewable Energy
Through Bulk Energy Storage (CAREBS)
California Public Utilities Commission
(CPUC)
Dayton Power and Light Company (Dayton)
Detroit Edison Company (Detroit Edison)
Dominion Resources Services, Inc.
(Dominion)
Duke Energy Corporation (Duke)
Environmental Defense Fund (EDF)
Edison Electric Institute (EEI)
Electricity Consumers Resource Council
(ELCON)
Electric Storage Association (ESA)
Jack Ellis
PO 00000
Frm 00027
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 9990
67285
ENBALA Power Networks (ENBALA)
EnerNOC, Inc. (EnerNOC)
Electric Power Supply Association (EPSA)
FirstEnergy Service Company (FirstEnergy)
Invenergy Wind Development LLC
(Invenergy)
ISO/RTO Council (IRC)
ISO New England Inc. (ISO–NE)
Manitoba Hydro
Midwest Independent System Operator, Inc.
(MISO)
Midwest Independent System Operator
Transmission Owners (MISO TOs)
Morgan Stanley Capital Group Inc. (Morgan
Stanley)
NaturEner USA, LLC (NaturEner)
Natural Gas Supply Association (NGSA)
New England Conference of Public Utilities
Commissioners (NECPUC)
New England Power Pool (NEPOOL)
New York Independent System Operator, Inc.
(NYISO)
New York Public Service Commission
(NYPSC)
New York Transmission Owners (NY TOs)
Occidental Chemical Corporation
(Occidental)
Organization of Midwest ISO States (OMS)
Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission
(PaPUC)
Pacific Gas and Electric Company (PG&E)
PJM Interconnection, L.L.C. (PJM)
Powerex Corporation (Powerex)
Primus Power (Primus)
Project for a Sustainable FERC Energy Policy
on Behalf of Public Interest Organizations
(PIO)
Recycled Energy Development (RED)
Southern California Edison Company (SoCal
Edison)
Starwood Energy Global Group, L.L.C and
Premium Power Corporation (Starwood/
Premium)
Steel Producers
SunEdison LLC (SunEdison)
Transmission Access Policy Study Group
(TAPS)
VCharge
Viridity Energy, Inc. (Viridity)
Xtreme Power, Inc. (Xtreme Power)
[FR Doc. 2011–27622 Filed 10–28–11; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6717–01–P
E:\FR\FM\31OCR2.SGM
31OCR2
Agencies
[Federal Register Volume 76, Number 210 (Monday, October 31, 2011)]
[Rules and Regulations]
[Pages 67260-67285]
From the Federal Register Online via the Government Printing Office [www.gpo.gov]
[FR Doc No: 2011-27622]
[[Page 67259]]
Vol. 76
Monday,
No. 210
October 31, 2011
Part II
Department of Energy
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
18 CFR Part 35
Frequency Regulation Compensation in the Organized Wholesale Power
Markets; Final Rule
Federal Register / Vol. 76 , No. 210 / Monday, October 31, 2011 /
Rules and Regulations
[[Page 67260]]
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
DEPARTMENT OF ENERGY
Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
18 CFR Part 35
[Docket Nos. RM11-7-000 and AD10-11-000; Order No. 755]
Frequency Regulation Compensation in the Organized Wholesale
Power Markets
AGENCY: Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, DOE.
ACTION: Final rule.
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
SUMMARY: Pursuant to section 206 of the Federal Power Act, the
Commission is revising its regulations to remedy undue discrimination
in the procurement of frequency regulation in the organized wholesale
electric markets and ensure that providers of frequency regulation
receive just and reasonable and not unduly discriminatory or
preferential rates. Frequency regulation service is one of the tools
regional transmission organizations (RTOs) and independent system
operators (ISOs) use to balance supply and demand on the transmission
system, maintaining reliable operations. In doing so, RTOs and ISOs
deploy a variety of resources to meet frequency regulation needs; these
resources differ in both their ramping ability, which is their ability
to increase or decrease their provision of frequency regulation
service, and the accuracy with which they can respond to the system
operator's dispatch signal.
The Commission finds that current frequency regulation compensation
practices of RTOs and ISOs result in rates that are unjust,
unreasonable, and unduly discriminatory or preferential. Specifically,
current compensation methods for regulation service in RTO and ISO
markets fail to acknowledge the inherently greater amount of frequency
regulation service being provided by faster-ramping resources. In
addition, certain practices of some RTOs and ISOs result in
economically inefficient economic dispatch of frequency regulation
resources.
By remedying these issues, the Commission is removing unduly
discriminatory and preferential practices from RTO and ISO tariffs and
requiring the setting of just and reasonable rates. Specifically, this
Final Rule requires RTOs and ISOs to compensate frequency regulation
resources based on the actual service provided, including a capacity
payment that includes the marginal unit's opportunity costs and a
payment for performance that reflects the quantity of frequency
regulation service provided by a resource when the resource is
accurately following the dispatch signal.
DATES: Effective Date: This Final Rule will become effective December
30, 2011.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: Robert Hellrich-Dawson (Technical
Information), Office of Energy Policy & Innovation, 888 First Street
NE., Washington, DC 20426, (202) 502-6360, bob.hellrich-dawson@ferc.gov. Eric Winterbauer (Legal Information), Office of the
General Counsel, 888 First Street NE., Washington, DC 20426, (202) 502-
8329, eric.winterbauer@ferc.gov.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION:
UNITED STATES OF AMERICA
FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION
Before Commissioners: Jon Wellinghoff, Chairman; Marc Spitzer,
Philip D. Moeller, John R. Norris, and Cheryl A. LaFleur.
Frequency Regulation Compensation in the Organized Wholesale Power
Markets Docket Nos. RM11-7-000; AD10-11-000
ORDER NO. 755
FINAL RULE
(Issued October 20, 2011)
1. Pursuant to section 206 of the Federal Power Act (FPA),\1\ the
Commission is revising its regulations to remedy undue discrimination
in the procurement of frequency regulation in the organized wholesale
electric markets and ensure that providers of frequency regulation
receive just and reasonable and not unduly discriminatory or
preferential rates. Frequency regulation service is one of the tools
regional transmission organizations (RTOs) and independent system
operators (ISOs) use to balance supply and demand on the transmission
system, maintaining reliable operations. In doing so, RTOs and ISOs \2\
deploy a variety of resources to meet frequency regulation needs; these
resources differ in both their ramping \3\ ability, which is their
ability to increase or decrease their provision of frequency regulation
service, and the accuracy with which they can respond to the system
operator's dispatch signal. In this instance, the ability to provide
more accurate frequency regulation service means to follow the system
operator's dispatch signal more closely.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1\ 16 U.S.C. 824e. Accord 16 U.S.C. 824d (providing that rates
must be just and reasonable).
\2\ The following RTOs and ISOs have organized wholesale
electricity markets: PJM Interconnection, LLC (PJM); New York
Independent System Operator, Inc. (NYISO); Midwest Independent
Transmission System Operator, Inc. (MISO); ISO New England Inc.
(ISO-NE); California Independent System Operator Corp. (CAISO); and
Southwest Power Pool, Inc. (SPP).
\3\ ``Ramping'' or the ability to ``ramp'' is traditionally
defined as the ability to change the output of real power from a
generating unit per some unit of time, usually measured as megawatts
per minute (MW/min). A generator ramps up to produce more energy and
ramps down to produce less. A storage device ramps up by discharging
energy and ramps down by charging. A demand response resource, in
the context of the provision of frequency regulation, ramps up by
consuming less energy and ramps down by consuming more.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
2. The Commission finds that current frequency regulation
compensation practices of RTOs and ISOs result in rates that are
unjust, unreasonable, and unduly discriminatory or preferential.
Specifically, current compensation methods for regulation service in
RTO and ISO markets fail to acknowledge the inherently greater amount
of frequency regulation service being provided by faster-ramping
resources.\4\ In addition, certain practices of some RTOs and ISOs
result in economically inefficient economic dispatch of frequency
regulation resources.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\4\ Both existing market participants and potential entrants are
affected by inefficient pricing. It is possible that existing market
participants would offer faster ramping capabilities to the system
operator in response to a pricing scheme that recognized such
service.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
3. By remedying these issues, the Commission is removing unduly
discriminatory and preferential practices from RTO and ISO tariffs and
requiring the setting of just and reasonable rates. Specifically, this
Final Rule requires RTOs and ISOs to compensate frequency regulation
resources based on the actual service provided, including a capacity
payment that includes the marginal unit's opportunity costs and a
payment for performance that reflects the quantity of frequency
regulation service provided by a resource when the resource is
accurately following the dispatch signal.
I. Background
A. Frequency Regulation Service
4. Frequency regulation\5\ service is the injection or withdrawal
of real power by facilities capable of responding
[[Page 67261]]
appropriately to a transmission system operator's automatic generator
control (AGC) signal. When dispatched generation does not equal actual
load plus losses on a moment-by-moment basis, the imbalance will cause
the grid's frequency to deviate from 60 Hertz, the standard in the U.S.
While the system does deviate from 60 Hz in the normal operation of the
grid, frequency deviations outside an acceptable range negatively
affect energy consuming devices; major deviations cause generation and
transmission equipment to disconnect from the grid, in the worst case
leading to a cascading blackout. Frequency regulation service can help
to prevent these adverse consequences by rapidly correcting deviations
in the transmission system's frequency to bring it within an acceptable
range.\6\ The system operator calibrates the AGC signal sent to
frequency regulation resources to respond to actual and anticipated
frequency deviations or interchange power imbalance, both measured by
area control error (ACE).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\5\ Frequency regulation, or secondary frequency control, is
distinguishable from frequency response, or primary frequency
control, for the purposes of this rulemaking. The latter, i.e.,
frequency response, involves the automatic, autonomous and rapid
action of turbine governor control to change a generator's output
and of demand response resources to change consumption in automatic
response to changes in frequency. This occurs independently of any
dispatch signal from a system operator. On January 20, 2011, the
Commission released for public comment a staff study evaluating the
use of frequency response metrics as a tool to assess the
reliability impacts of varying resource mixes on the transmission
grid.
\6\ A balancing authority achieves acceptable ranges by being in
compliance with Control Performance Standards 1 and 2 as defined in
the Commission-approved Reliability Standard BAL-001-0.1a.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
5. Today, frequency regulation is largely provided by generators
(e.g., water, steam and combustion turbines) that are specially
equipped for this purpose. Provision by other resources is emerging, as
technologies develop and tariff and market rules adapt to accommodate
new resources. For example, the Texas Interconnection and MISO
currently use controllable demand response in addition to generators to
provide frequency regulation service. Such ``regulation capable''
generation, storage devices, and demand response resources can respond
automatically to signals sent by the RTO or ISO, through AGC, to
increase or decrease real power injections or withdrawals and thereby
correct actual or anticipated frequency deviations or interchange
schedule imbalance, as measured by the ACE. The faster a resource can
ramp up or down, the more accurately it can respond to the AGC signal
and avoid overshooting.\7\ Alternatively, when a resource ramps too
slowly, its ramping limitations may cause it to work against the needs
of the system and force the system operator to commit additional
regulation resources to compensate.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\7\ See Beacon Power Corporation (Beacon), Technical Conference
Speaker Materials, at Figure 3, which shows the difference between
ISO-NE's ACE control signal, Beacon's flywheel response, and the
allowable response rate under current ISO-NE rules. Here,
``allowable response rate'' means the rate at which the resource
must respond to be considered in compliance with the dispatch
signal. Frequency Regulation Compensation in the Organized Wholesale
Power Markets, Docket No. AD10-11-000 (May 26, 2010).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
B. Current RTO and ISO Compensation Practices
6. In the RTO and ISO markets, compensation for frequency
regulation service is presently based on several components. Depending
on the RTO or ISO, these payments include consideration for capacity
set aside to provide the service \8\ as well as some of the following:
the net energy that the resource injects into the system; accurately
following the RTO's or ISO's dispatch signal; and the absolute (rather
than net) amount of energy injected or withdrawn. These payments are
intended to cover the range of costs incurred in providing frequency
regulation service, e.g., operation and maintenance costs, and loss of
potential revenue from foregone sales of electricity.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\8\ This type of capacity payment is distinguishable from
capacity payments associated with the procurement of resources to
meet planning reserve margin requirements.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
7. The payment for capacity is essentially an option payment to the
resource to keep a certain amount of capacity out of the energy or
other markets in order to provide frequency regulation service,
typically based on a market clearing price per MW of capacity sold.
ISO-NE, NYISO, MISO, California ISO, and PJM incorporate into this
payment the opportunity cost of foregone energy sales incurred by a
resource that provides frequency regulation service. However, ISO-NE
and PJM do not apply the opportunity cost payment uniformly to all
cleared resources, but rather make ex post resource-specific
opportunity cost payments.
8. Compensation for frequency regulation service also includes
payments or charges for the net energy the resource injects into or
withdraws from the system. All RTOs and ISOs currently provide a
payment for the net energy injected by a resource providing regulation
service during the operating hour, calculated as the amount of energy
injected less energy withdrawn multiplied by the real-time energy
price.
9. Accuracy of performance can also be incorporated into payments
for frequency regulation service. Currently, NYISO incorporates
accuracy into its compensation for frequency regulation service through
a penalty that reflects the accuracy with which the resource follows
its dispatch instruction.\9\ This is done through a performance index
that tracks how accurately a resource follows the dispatch signal.\10\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\9\ NYISO, Ancillary Services Manual, Manual 2 (Nov. 2010),
https://www.nyiso.com/public/webdocs/documents/manuals/operations/ancserv.pdf.
\10\ NYISO uses telemetry data to track how closely a frequency
regulation resource's output is to the dispatch signal. NYISO then
adjusts the resource's payments to reflect its accuracy. For
example, if the resource's response falls outside an acceptable
range 10 percent of the time, for a performance index of 0.9, it
will receive 90 percent of its payment.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
10. ISO-NE makes payments for frequency regulation service to
reflect the amount of work performed by a resource by reflecting the
absolute amount of energy injected and withdrawn, sometimes referred to
as a ``mileage'' payment. Mileage payments are intended to reward those
resources that perform more regulation service instead of simply
netting the total amount of energy injected by the resource.\11\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\11\ ISO-NE., Market Operations Manual M-11, at 3-11 (Dec.
2010), available at https://www.iso-ne.com/rules_proceds/isone_mnls/m_11_market_operations_revision_35_12_01_10.doc.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
11. In general, when a resource submits its frequency regulation
bid to the RTO or ISO, the bid is typically required to include its
ramp rate in MW/min, its cost per megawatt-hours (MWh) of ramping
ability, and the total capacity it is offering for frequency
regulation.\12\ The resource's total amount of capacity is based on and
limited by its ability to ramp up or down.\13\ For example, a resource
with a relatively large amount of capacity, but a relatively slow ramp
rate would be limited in how much capacity it could offer as frequency
regulation capacity. If the resource can ramp one MW per minute, it
would only be able to offer five MW of regulation capacity (for a five
minute dispatch) regardless of its total capacity. On the other hand, a
smaller capacity, faster ramping resource might not face such a
constraint. For instance, a storage device that can hold a 20 MW charge
and ramp at 10 MW per minute, could offer its full 20 MW of capacity
for five minutes.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\12\ See, e.g., NYISO, Ancillary Services Manual, Manual 2, at
4-8 (Nov. 2010).
\13\ A resource's capacity is limited by the amount it can ramp
in five minutes because the system operator in most RTOs and ISOs
dispatch resources every five minutes. CAISO dispatches every 10
minutes, and so a frequency regulation resource's capacity in that
market is bound by the total capacity it can ramp in 10 minutes.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
12. The Commission recognizes that some RTOs and ISOs are
considering changes to their frequency regulation markets.\14\ For
example, in February of
[[Page 67262]]
this year PJM established a ``Regulation Performance Senior Task
Force'' to examine the existing PJM regulation market's inability to
distinguish between resources' various levels of performance and the
absence of additional compensation for the resources to perform at a
high level once they have qualified for the regulation market.\15\
Therefore, the Commission believes that this Final Rule is timely, in
that it will help guide these various stakeholder processes.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\14\ In addition to the examples cited here, SPP is in the
process of developing its integrated marketplace that will include a
day-ahead market and consolidated ancillary services market.
\15\ See PJM Regulation Performance Senior Task Force Charter at
1 (2011) and ISO-NE., Report of ISO New England Inc. Regarding the
Implementation of Market Rule Changes to Permit Non-Generating
Resources to Participate in the Regulation Market, Docket No. ER08-
54-014, at 5 (June 17, 2010).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
C. Commission Inquiries Leading to This Rulemaking
13. On May 26, 2010, the Commission hosted a publicly noticed
technical conference \16\ inviting various stakeholders, including
representatives from the RTOs and ISOs, industry, and academia to share
their views on whether current frequency regulation market designs
reflect the value of the service provided, and whether the use of
faster-ramping resources for frequency regulation has the potential to
provide benefits to the organized markets.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\16\ See Final Agenda, Frequency Regulation Compensation in the
Organized Wholesale Power Markets, Docket No. AD10-11-000 (May 26,
2010).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
14. On February 17, 2011, the Commission issued a Notice of
Proposed Rulemaking in this proceeding,\17\ seeking comment on its
proposal to require both a uniform price for frequency regulation
capacity paid to all cleared resources as well as a performance payment
for the provision of frequency regulation service, with the latter
payment reflecting a resource's accuracy of performance.\18\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\17\ Frequency Regulation Compensation in the Organized
Wholesale Power Markets, 76 FR 11,177, 134 FERC ] 61,124 (2011)
(NOPR).
\18\ See Appendix for a list of commenters.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
II. Discussion
A. The Need for Reform
15. As discussed below, the Commission finds that current frequency
regulation compensation practices in organized wholesale electricity
markets which fail to compensate resources for all of the service they
provide as part of that service are unjust, unreasonable, and unduly
discriminatory or preferential.
1. NOPR Preliminary Finding
a. Unduly Discriminatory Pricing
16. In the NOPR, the Commission stated that the current rules that
govern pricing and compensation for frequency regulation services in
RTOs and ISOs may be unduly discriminatory, because resources are
compensated at the same level even when providing different amounts of
frequency regulation service.\19\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\19\ NOPR, 134 FERC ] 61,124 at P 27.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
17. Specifically, the Commission was concerned that under some
existing frequency regulation compensation methods, resources may not
be compensated for all of the service they provide even when given
preference in the dispatch order and asked to provide more frequency
regulation service than other resources. The Commission noted, for
example, that CAISO, NYISO, MISO, and PJM pay a capacity payment to all
resources that clear the frequency regulation market, and then net the
amount of regulation up and regulation down provided by these resources
in order to compensate for the energy costs they incur. The Commission
preliminarily found that this compensation method does not acknowledge
the greater amount of frequency regulation service being provided by
faster-ramping resources.\20\ It stated that, as a result, slower-
responding resources are compensated as if they are providing the same
amount of service when, in reality, they are not,\21\ and that slower,
larger resources are being given a compensatory advantage for their
size while faster, smaller resources do not similarly receive
compensation for their ramping speed and actual service provided.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\20\ A simplified example would be to consider two resources
that clear with the same amount of capacity and are directed to
provide regulation up and regulation down over the course of a five-
minute interval. The fast-ramping resource might be directed to move
around an initial output level up five MW, then down three MW, up
one MW, down ten MW, and finally up nine MW. A netting approach to
compensation would determine that the resource provided an
additional two MW of energy to the system (+ 5 - 3 + 1 - 10 + 9 = +
2) during that five minute interval. Meanwhile, a slower-ramping
resource may be directed to move up three MW and then down one MW
for a net of two MW in relation to its initial output level. The
operator is not able to direct more movement because the slower-
ramping resource would not be able to respond in the requisite time
frame. Both resources would receive identical compensation for their
movement, despite the first resource providing more ACE correction.
\21\ NOPR, 134 FERC ] 61,124 at P 28.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
18. The Commission also expressed concern that the manner in which
some resources that provide frequency regulation service are
compensated for their opportunity costs \22\ may be unduly
discriminatory.\23\ For instance, while PJM provides an ex ante
estimate of opportunity costs that is included in the uniform clearing
price, it also provides ex post ``make whole'' payments based on
individual unit opportunity costs, something that is not reflected in
the uniform market clearing price calculation; \24\ ISO-NE pays
opportunity costs on a resource-specific basis so that the market-
clearing price for frequency regulation service does not reflect any
opportunity costs. Both of these methods have the potential to
inefficiently select regulating resources and also fail to reflect the
marginal cost (including opportunity cost) that determines the market-
clearing price paid to all cleared suppliers. Therefore, the NOPR
proposed to require that all resource bids include opportunity costs
and that all cleared frequency regulation resources be paid the single
market clearing price, which reflects the total marginal costs of the
marginal cleared unit.\25\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\22\ When participating in the energy and frequency regulation
markets, a resource is dispatched at a set-point below its maximum
capacity. Because this amount of capacity is held in reserve to
provide frequency regulation, the resource misses the opportunity to
provide energy at the current LMP.
\23\ NOPR, 134 FERC ] 61,124 at P 31.
\24\ PJM, Manual 18: Operating Agreement Accounting, at 12-16,
available at https://www.pjm.com/~/media/documents/manuals/m28.ashx.
\25\ NOPR, 134 FERC ] 61,124 at P 31.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
b. Potential Market Efficiency Gains
19. The NOPR also preliminarily found that the use of faster-
ramping resources for frequency regulation has the potential to improve
operational and economic efficiency and, in turn, lower costs to
consumers in the organized markets. Faster-ramping resources may be
able to replace resources that currently provide frequency regulation,
so that RTOs and ISOs may be able to procure less regulation capacity,
thereby lowering costs to load.
2. Comments
a. Unduly Discriminatory Pricing
20. Many commenters expressly support the NOPR's proposed
performance payment to reflect the amount of frequency regulation
provided by a resource.\26\ They
[[Page 67263]]
generally argue that for a frequency regulation compensation mechanism
to be just and reasonable it must compensate providers for the service
they actually provide to the grid. They argue that the compensation
systems currently used in the RTOs and ISOs are not only unduly
discriminatory but also problematic because they send inefficient price
signals. In addition, they generally advocate that a performance
payment for regulation will incent participants to offer more
flexibility to the system operator and will compensate resources for
the value they provide the grid.\27\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\26\ A123, Alcoa, Beacon, CESA, Duke, ESA, EDF, EPSA, ELCON,
ENBALA, EnerNOC, Invenergy, ISO-NE., Manitoba Hydro, MISO, MSCG,
NaturEner, NECPUC, NEPOOL, OMS, PaPUC, PG&E, Powerex, Primus Power,
PIOs, PJM, SoCal Edison, Starwood/Premium, SunEdison, VCharge,
Viridity, and Xtreme Power all submitted comments supporting the
proposal to require a performance payment. Some have offered
alternative means to accomplish the same goal, as described below.
\27\ See, e.g., EDF May 2, 2011 Comments at P 14 and P 16, CESA
May 2, 2011 Comments at 2 and 8, ENBALA May 2, 2011 Comments at 8,
ELCON May 2, 2011 Comments at 4, Manitoba Hydro April 27, 2011
Comments at 2 (citing Prowse, D. ``Improvements to a Standard
Automatic Generation Control Filter Algorithm'' IEEE/PES Summer
Power Meeting, 92 SM 451-5 PWRS), OMS May 2, 2011 Comments at 6,
Primus Power April 18, 2011 Comments at 5-6, PIOs May 3, 2011
Comments at 5-7, PJM May 2, 2011 Comments at 6, SoCal Edison May 2,
2011 Comments at 3, Starwood/Premium May 2, 2011 Comments at 4-5,
Viridity May 2, 2011 Comments at 1, Xtreme Power May 2, 2011
Comments at 6-7.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
21. Alcoa supports the proposal that compensation for frequency
regulation service reflect the absolute (rather than net) energy the
resource injects into or withdraws from the system. Alcoa states that
compensating for the amount of movement creates strong market signals
because it ensures that those resources that are performing more work
to correct system deviations are rewarded more. It contends that this
aligns with the physical reality that the more the resource is moved,
the more wear will occur on the equipment and the higher the cost of
supplying the service.\28\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\28\ Alcoa May 2, 2011 Comments at 3-4.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
22. Beacon contends that, currently, all resources (except in ISO-
NE), regardless of how frequently they are deployed or how much of the
ACE correction they provide, are paid the same price per MW for their
capacity offered. Beacon contends that no payment is based on how much
the resource is actually deployed to provide frequency regulation.\29\
Beacon argues that this is unjust and unreasonable. Similarly, PIOs
argue that NYISO's and MISO's frequency regulation markets fail to
ensure just and reasonable treatment of faster-ramping regulation
resources, and do not provide the proper economic incentive for
efficient market participation.\30\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\29\ Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 20-21, ESA May 2, 2011
Comments at 19-20.
\30\ PIOs May 2, 2011 Comments at P 16.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
23. In order to illustrate the undue discrimination that can occur
in frequency regulation markets, Beacon provides data from its own 1 MW
flywheel operating in the ISO-NE market, contending that these data
demonstrate that its resource provides more than four times as much
frequency regulation service to ISO-NE as would a 1 MW resource with an
allowable ramp rate of 1 MW/5 minutes.\31\ It contends that the
flywheel provides 0.48 MWh while the slower ramping resource provides
0.11 MWh. Beacon states that the reason its flywheel is able to provide
more frequency regulation service is not just because of its faster
ramping ability, but also because it is able to switch the direction of
the resource nearly instantaneously.\32\ In a frequency regulation
market paying only a capacity payment, Beacon's flywheel will have
performed a greater amount of frequency regulation service, yet
received the same payment as the other resource.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\31\ Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 6-7. These data are the same
data on which the table in Appendix A of the NOPR is based.
\32\ Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 7.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
24. Beacon and ESA argue that a performance payment system is
needed in order to send efficient price signals and to compensate
resources that are asked to do more work. Beacon and ESA maintain that
this form of pricing will appropriately compensate resources and
encourage the RTOs and ISOs to improve operational and economic
efficiencies, thereby lowering costs to consumers.\33\ In support of
its arguments, Beacon points to operating data from its flywheel in
NYISO comparing the actual performance of its flywheel to a
hypothetical, similarly sized slower resource to determine how much
each resource would contribute to frequency regulation service.\34\
Beacon states that even though the flywheel would have been dispatched
to provide more than twelve times as much frequency regulation service,
its flywheel would have actually been paid less than the slower-
responding resource that provided less service to the system.\35\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\33\ Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 26-27, ESA May 2, 2011
Comments at 24-25.
\34\ See Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 22-24.
\35\ Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 24 (citing NYISO Tariff,
Section 15.3.2.1(d), Regulation Service Offers from Limited Energy
Storage Resources. ``The ISO may reduce the real-time Regulation
Service offer (in MWs) from a Limited Energy Storage Resource to
account for the Energy storage capacity of such Resource.''). See
also ESA May 2, 2011 Comments at 21-23 (providing a numerical
example of how a two-part payment system can result in cost savings
in the procurement of frequency regulation capacity and service).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
25. Beacon also provides an example of five 20 MW resources with
different ramp rates--two average resources, two slower resources, and
one faster resource--that are dispatched and paid based only on the
amount of capacity offered. Beacon asserts that if these resources were
to be paid for both capacity and performance, the system operator could
reduce the amount of capacity procured by 40 percent while obtaining
the same amount of regulation service. Assuming a $10 decrease in the
capacity price and a $1.00/MW mileage rate, Beacon estimates a
reduction in total regulation cost of 27 percent, in addition to
releasing 40 MW of generation to provide energy or other reserves.\36\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\36\ Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 33-36.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
26. PJM states that it strongly supports a performance-based
methodology. PJM claims that a performance payment provides an
appropriate incentive to provide high quality regulation service by
tying a portion of the total compensation to a resource's performance.
In addition, PJM asserts that a performance payment will ensure
resources provide accurate responses to control signals, in contrast
with the current structure that provides no incentive to perform above
a minimum threshold.\37\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\37\ PJM May 2, 2011 Comments at 6.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
27. Among the RTOs and ISOs, only CAISO makes the claim that its
markets are not unduly discriminatory or preferential. CAISO asserts
that the Commission cannot declare the existing rate unjust and
unreasonable or unduly discriminatory based on an unsupported
conclusion that all markets require more ACE correction.\38\ Indeed,
CAISO argues that its operational and reliability requirements,
including ACE correction, have been and continue to be adequately met
by existing regulation services and resources. Furthermore, CAISO
argues that its rates for regulation apply to all resources equally so
long as the resource meets the minimum operating and technical
requirements to provide regulation because the amount of capacity a
resource may bid for regulation is based upon the resource's certified
ramp rate over a ten minute interval. It contends that, therefore, a
faster-ramping resource can sell more regulation capacity than a slower
ramping resource. It argues that these terms and conditions of service
provide comparable treatment for all resources certified to provide
regulation.\39\ CAISO also argues that while its energy management
system does not include a priority dispatch for resources with faster-
ramping capability, its system will send control
[[Page 67264]]
signals to faster ramping resources if it requires a fast response to
correct ACE. Control signals are sent in part based on a resource's
operating range and ramping capability.\40\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\38\ CAISO May 2, 2011 Comments at 6-7.
\39\ CAISO May 2, 2011 Comments at 8.
\40\ Id. at 9.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
28. Some commenters argue that the Commission has failed to show a
sufficient basis for exercising its section 206 authority to mandate
revisions to existing RTO and ISO tariff provisions.\41\ CAISO argues
it has and continues to meet its operational and reliability
requirements, and pays equally all resources capable to meet the
requirement. As such, CAISO argues, its markets are not unduly
discriminatory or preferential.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\41\ EEI May 2, 2011 Comments at 9-10, TAPS May 2, 2011 Comments
at 5.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
29. EEI contends that the Commission has not shown that changing
the compensation mechanism to increase compensation for faster ramping
resources will result in enhanced reliability or enable system
operators to more easily meet reliability standards; that the
Commission is looking at only one of the three elements of frequency
response (inertial response and governor response being the others) and
in doing so has failed to provide the necessary technical basis to
demonstrate that its assumptions that resources providing frequency
regulation are more valuable than resources providing the other
services and that the resulting payments are unduly discriminatory.
Similarly, NGSA argues that regulatory policies that focus singly on
special forms of compensation and incentives for some forms of
ancillary and balancing services, but not others, are likely to result
in distorted market signals and a mix of services and products that are
sub-optimal for meeting system balancing requirements. NGSA contends
that there is a direct interrelationship between primary and secondary
frequency control, and compensation for frequency regulation cannot be
considered in isolation.\42\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\42\ NGSA May 2, 2011 Comments at 4.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
30. TAPS also argues that the existing total compensation for
frequency regulation has not been shown to be unjust and unreasonable.
TAPS contends that any increased payments to faster-ramping resources
must be balanced by savings through reduced regulation procurement or
lower payments to slower resources, such that costs to consumers are
reduced.\43\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\43\ TAPS May 2, 2011 Comments at 5.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
31. Duke argues that the Commission should not favor or subsidize
one type of resource over another.\44\ It contends that both fast- and
slow-ramping resources have a role to play and there will be instances
when operators will not need faster-ramping resources to address
frequency deviations. As an example, Duke states that there will be a
need for slower-ramping resources that ramp with the load over a five
minute period (e.g., load following).\45\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\44\ See also CAREBS May 2, 2011 Comments at 5-6, AWEA May 2,
2011 Comments at 3-4, Duke May 2, 2011 Comments at 4-5, ELCON May 2,
2011 Comments at 6, SoCal Edison May 2, 2011 Comments at 6.
\45\ Duke May 2, 2011 Comments at 4-6.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
32. EEI argues that the Commission failed to support the NOPR
proposal as just and reasonable, because, according to EEI, the
Commission did not explain how the two-part payment mechanism will
enhance reliability or make compliance with reliability rules easier or
cheaper for system operators. EEI claims that no substantial pilot
programs have been conducted to evaluate the system cost and
reliability impacts of substituting non-traditional resources for
existing resources. EEI suggests that the Commission encourage the
development of network pilot programs before requiring a revision of
frequency regulation service.\46\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\46\ EEI May 2, 2011 Comments at 9.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
33. Several commenters express concern that the Commission will act
prematurely, without a full record addressing the various issues to
which the NOPR was addressed.\47\ For example, NGSA, among others,
cited Commissioner Spitzer's dissent to the NOPR, arguing that feedback
is needed from a broad spectrum of industry participants; otherwise the
record on which to make the proposed changes to the Commission's
regulations may be undermined.\48\ The NY TOs contend that the record
is insufficient to support a conclusion that the NYISO-administered
markets fail to adequately compensate fast response resources.\49\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\47\ CAISO May 2, 2011 Comments at 11-12, Duke May 2, 2011
Comments at 2, EEI May 2, 2011 Comments at 10 (supported by Dayton,
Detroit Edison, and FirstEnergy), Jack Ellis May 2, 2011 Comments at
7, MISO TOs May 2, 2011 Comments at 5.
\48\ Natural Gas Supply Association May 2, 2011 Comments at 5.
\49\ New York Transmission Owners May 2, 2011 Comments at 1.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
b. Potential Market Benefits
34. The primary economic benefit that some commenters expect to see
is reduced costs of procuring frequency regulation capacity, with a
secondary benefit of reduced energy costs.\50\ Commenters argue that
faster-ramping resources are able to provide more frequency regulation
service from the same amount of frequency regulation capacity because
faster-ramping resources can provide more ACE correction in real-time.
Commenters conclude that this will result in a system operator needing
to procure less frequency regulation capacity.\51\ Commenters further
explain that, as these faster-responding resources displace slower-
ramping resources, existing generators that are displaced can be
shifted to provide an even greater amount of energy. These traditional
resources can then run at their full capacity at their preferred
steady-state operating point which improves their heat rate and reduces
the wear and tear on their equipment, thereby lowering their cost to
operate.\52\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\50\ See, e.g., Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 5, ESA May 2,
2011 Comments at 3, EDF May 2, 2011 Comments at P 5-7, EDF May 2,
2011 Comments at P 9, ENBALA May 3, 2011 Comments at 3, NEPOOL May
2, 2011 Comments at 6, PaPUC May 2, 2011 Comments at 5, PJM May 2,
2011 Comments at 3-4.
\51\ SoCal Edison May 2, 2011 Comments at 3.
\52\ Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 11, CESA May 2, 2011
Comments at 5, ENBALA May 3, 2011 Comments at 4, ESA May 2, 2011
Comments at 11, and PaPUC May 2, 2011 Comments at 5 and Snowberger
Affidavit at 8.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
35. Commenters cite several studies to support the argument that
faster-responding resources will result in economic benefits. Among
them is PNNL's study showing that fast-ramping energy storage resources
(such as flywheels and batteries) could be as much as 17 times more
effective than conventional ramp-limited regulation resources because
of how quickly and accurately they respond to a system imbalance; \53\
and a California Energy Commission study which showed that ``on an
incremental basis, storage can be up to two to three times as effective
as adding a combustion turbine to the system for regulation purposes.''
\54\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\53\ Makarov, Y.V., Ma, J., Lu, S., Nguyen, T.B., ``Assessing
the value of Regulation Resources Based on Their Time Response
Characteristics,'' Pacific Northwest National Laboratory, PNNL--
17632, June 2008.
\54\ Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 8-9 (citing KEMA, ``Research
Evaluation of Wind Generation, Solar Generation, and Storage Impact
on the California Grid'' (prepared for the California Energy
Commission), June, 2010).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
36. Commenters also pointed to ISO-NE and NYISO as examples of
markets that have a relatively high number of faster-responding
frequency regulation resources. In both cases, the system operator is
able to procure a relatively smaller amount of frequency regulation
capacity, compared to other RTOs and ISOs. Beacon notes that ISO-NE.
the only RTO or ISO to both dispatch faster-ramping resources first and
then compensate resources based on performance, is able to procure the
least frequency regulation capacity, measured
[[Page 67265]]
as a percentage of peak load.\55\ EDF also notes that ISO-NE and NYISO,
two balancing authority areas with relatively high concentrations of
faster-responding resources, procure relatively less frequency
regulation capacity.\56\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\55\ Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 9-10. See also ESA May 2,
2011 Comments at 9-10.
\56\ EDF May 2, 2011 Comments at P 8.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
37. ISO-NE agrees that fast-ramping resources provide benefits in
the regulation market and states that the participation of fast-ramping
resources in the New England regulation market is a factor in New
England's low current regulation requirement. ISO-NE also states that
all other things being equal, faster response is clearly better than
slower response, for the reasons explained in the NOPR. PJM also argues
the importance of procuring a mix of frequency regulation resources,
some of which will have the ability to sustainably maintain their
response.\57\ Likewise, SoCal Edison states that the use of faster-
ramping regulation resources, in conjunction with an efficient
regulation dispatch algorithm and effective unit compliance with the
dispatch signal should reduce the total amount of regulation capacity
needed to perform regulation service.\58\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\57\ PJM May 2, 2011 Comments at 4.
\58\ SoCal Edison May 2, 2011 Comments at 3.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
38. PIOs state that PJM estimates that a 10 percent or 20 percent
reduction in its frequency regulation capacity procurement could result
in a $25 million or $50 million, respectively, reduction in costs to
consumers. PIOs state that this savings is large in comparison to the
modest software costs required to implement these market rules.\59\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\59\ PIOs May 2, 2011 Comments at P 20 (citing PJM Staff,
``Problem Statement,'' Jan. 19, 2011), available at https://
www.pjm.com/~/media/committees-groups/committees/mrc/20110216/
20110216-item-05-regulation-resource-performance-problem-
statement.ashx. The Problem Statement was presented to the PJM
Markets and Reliability Committee, and led to the establishment of a
PJM Regulation Performance Senior Task Force.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
39. To illustrate the potential benefits of faster-ramping
resources providing frequency regulation service, Primus Power extends
the Beacon Power example \60\ to one that applies more generally.
Primus Power simulates the output of both what they define as a
traditional resource and a fast-response resource. Both resources were
assumed to have a capacity of 1 MW; the traditional resource could ramp
1 MW in 5 minutes, while the faster-response resource could ramp
faster, mimicking the actual ability of a Primus Power energy storage
resource. Primus Power's result supports that of Beacon, with the
faster-responding resource following the AGC signal nearly perfectly,
while the slower-ramping resource lags to the point of working against
needed ACE correction.\61\ Primus Power claims that this results in the
faster-ramping resource providing approximately 76 percent more ACE
correction.\62\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\60\ Primus Power May 2, 2011 Comments at 2.
\61\ Id. at 3.
\62\ Id. at 5.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
40. Commenters also mention the potential for reliability benefits
stemming from the NOPR proposal. A123, Alcoa, Beacon, CESA, ESA, PIOs,
and PJM all state that system operators can also expect to see
reliability benefits from the integration of more faster-responding
resources. PIOs state that the integration of more faster-responding
resources will result in enhanced reliability because their ability to
more quickly and accurately follow dispatch instructions will allow the
system operator to better maintain system balance. Further, PIOs state
that the concern over sustainability is unfounded. First, PIOs state
that there is little reason to believe that faster-responding resources
will completely displace traditional resources in the short or near
term. Second, PIOs state that, given the short dispatch window system
operators use, i.e. 5 or 10 minute dispatch intervals, storage systems
can be assured of maintaining appropriate charge.\63\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\63\ PIOs May 2, 2011 Comments at P 22-23.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
41. Xtreme Power argues that the advantages of fast response
storage systems is that they do not have problems such as efficiency
degradation, emissions, exposure to peaking fuel prices, accelerated
O&M, and typical siting issues. Xtreme Power also states that fast
response storage systems do not require air quality permits like
conventional fossil-fired generation resources, and can therefore be
deployed to satisfy RTO or ISO needs for additional regulation service
more quickly than new fossil-fired generation.\64\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\64\ Xtreme Power May 2, 2011 Comments at 4-5.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
42. A123 presents data from ERCOT indicating that incorporating
storage resources capable of responding to a ``ramp-focused'' signal
from the system operator will result in net ACE remaining within
allowable NERC standards 100 percent of the time (as opposed to only 71
percent of the time when relying on traditional resources responding to
a slower signal). A123 argues that this improvement will provide the
system operator with a larger reliability margin. A123 presents this
analysis as an illustration of the difference between traditional
slower-ramping, unlimited energy resources and faster-ramping, limited
energy resources.\65\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\65\ A123 May 2, 2011 Comments at 6.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
43. Alcoa contends that the NOPR proposal is likely to result in
increased efficient operation of demand side resources and therefore a
decrease in the amount of resources dedicated to frequency regulation
service.\66\ Alcoa contends that there are reliability benefits from
integrating more direct load control demand response into system
operations because these resources can ramp faster and therefore help
restore system frequency more rapidly in the event of a system upset.
Alcoa states that because this response can happen within seconds, it
can help avert cascading system instability.\67\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\66\ Alcoa May 2, 2011 Comments at 5.
\67\ Id. at 4.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
44. PJM states that the use of faster-ramping resources will
enhance system control. Better control will then lead to a reduction in
uncompensated flows imposed on the system by a given balancing
authority and will provide better individual control by that balancing
authority.\68\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\68\ PJM May 2, 2011 Comments at 3.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
45. Beacon and ESA agree that the use of faster-ramping resources
can result in reliability benefits, based on the expectation that the
United States will add 145,000 MW of wind generation to the grid over
the next ten years. They argue that this will result in increased
supply variability, requiring increased system flexibility.\69\ In the
same vein, Beacon and ESA both cite CAISO's 20 percent renewable
portfolio standard study, which showed that CAISO will require an
additional 37 percent of regulation up and 11 percent of regulation
down in the summer season.\70\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\69\ Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 11-12, ESA May 2, 2011
Comments at 11, (citing Rick Sergel, President and CEO, North
American Electric Reliability Corporation, Executive Remarks, FERC
Technical Conference on Integrating Renewable Resources into the
Wholesale Electric Grid, March 2, 2009).
\70\ Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 12, ESA May 2, 2011 Comments
at 11-12 (citing CAISO, ``Integration of Renewable Resources:
Operational Requirements and Generation Fleet Capability at 20%
RPS,'' at 52, table 3.3 (2010), available at: https://www.caiso.com/2804/2804d036401f0.pdf).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
46. In addition Beacon and ESA assert that NYISO expects to need
increased regulation and reserve resources as more wind is integrated
into its system.\71\ Beacon, CESA, and ESA also points to the
Commission-sponsored, Lawrence Berkeley National Laboratory (LBNL)
[[Page 67266]]
report that identified reliability concerns due to the declining
frequency responsiveness of the US interconnections. In order to
address these reliability concerns, LBNL recommends expanding the
frequency control capability of the RTO and ISO interconnections using
advanced technologies such as energy storage.\72\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\71\ Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 12, ESA May 2, 2011 Comments
at 11 (citing NYISO, ``Integration of Wind into System Dispatch
White Paper,'' October 2008).
\72\ Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 13-14, CESA May 2, 2011
Comments at 6, ESA May 2, 2011 Comments at 13-14 (citing Joseph H.
Eto, Use of Frequency Response Metrics to Assess the Planning and
Operating Requirements for Reliable Integration of Variable
Renewable Generation Lawrence Berkeley National Laboratory, LBNL-
4142E, 2010, available at https://certs.lbl.gov/pdf/lbnl-4142e.pdf).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
47. Certain commenters \73\ argue that the integration of
additional faster-responding resources into the mix of frequency
regulation resources will result in environmental benefits. For
example, Beacon, CESA, and ESA cite to a 2007 KEMA and an October 2008
Carnegie Mellon University study in support. The KEMA study
demonstrated that continued reliance on thermal generating units to
meet increased regulation requirements could actually increase
emissions of carbon dioxide (CO2), nitrogen oxides
(NOX) and other pollutants, thereby defeating one of the
main benefits of wind generation.\74\ The Carnegie Mellon University
study estimated that 20 percent of the CO2 emission
reduction and up 100 percent of the NOX emission reduction
expected from introducing wind and solar power will be lost because of
the extra ramping requirements they impose on traditional
generation.\75\ Finally, CPUC states that while the Commission's
proposal is resource-neutral, it provides an economic incentive for
resources to assist in reducing greenhouse gas emissions, compensate
for variability of intermittent resources, and reduce costs to
consumers through decreased regulation procurement requirements.\76\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\73\ See e.g., EDF May 2, 2011 Comments at P10.
\74\ Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 13, CESA May 2, 2011
Comments at 5, and ESA May 2, 2011 Comments at 12-13 (citing KEMA,
Emissions Comparison for a 20MW Flywheel-based Frequency Regulation
Power Plant, May 18, 2007).
\75\ Beacon May 2, 2011 Comments at 13, ESA May 2, 2011 Comments
at 13 (citing Katzenstein, W., and Jay Apt. Air Emissions Due To
Wind and Solar Power. Environmental Science & Technology. 2009, 43,
253-258. (available at https://pubs.acs.org/doi/pdf/10.1021/es801437t)).
\76\ CPUC May 2, 2011 Comments at 2-3.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
48. Other commenters offer cautious support. For example, while
Duke Energy concurs that the faster-ramping resource should be
compensated for the actual amount of work that it performs, it cautions
that faster-ramping resources may not always be needed, and that
micromanaging power swings with faster resources may even result in
over-control of the system.\77\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\77\ Duke May 2, 2011 Comments at 7.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
49. Some commenters argue that the Commission has not justified the
increased costs that its compensation proposal may impose on load
serving entities and other network integration transmission service
customers.\78\ Others state that the Commission failed to consider the
impact on customers, who EEI states will ultimately bear the greatest
share of costs, by balancing increased payments to faster ramping
resources with savings through reduced regulation procurement or lower
payments to slower resources. As a result, EEI argues, load will likely
pay more for regulation service without any demonstrated reliability
benefit or decrease in the need for other resources.\79\ NY TOs, for
example, request that the Commission require NYISO to estimate the net
savings to consumers that would result if offering incentives for
increased participation by dedicated frequency regulation resources
induces more traditional capacity to shift away from the regulation
market and into the energy market.\80\ NaturEner requests that the
Commission be vigilant against possible unintended consequences, such
as increasing frequency regulation cost or requiring a greater volume
of frequency regulation resources.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\78\ EEI May 2, 2011 Comments at 12, TAPS May 2, 2011 Comments
at 4-5; Invenergy May 2, 2011 Comments at 2-3.
\79\ EEI May 2, 2011 Comments at 12.
\80\ NY TOs May 2, 2011 Comments at 5.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
50. Invenergy cautions the Commission to evaluate whether
alternative compensation structures, in addition to being higher cost,
will also result in better quality regulation, lower quantities of
regulation, and improved reliability.\81\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\81\ Invenergy May 2, 2011 Comments at 2-3.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
51. EPSA states that while it supports RTOs and ISOs employing a
mileage component similar to that employed in the ISO-NE regulation
market, that measure should be used to meet the objectives of
regulation service and not require incremental performance levels,
which do not yield incremental benefits.\82\ EPSA states that adequate
frequency is being achieved currently under NERC ACE control standards
through reliability requirement CPS1 by each of the RTO and ISO
balancing authorities. Thus, EPSA encourages the Commission to
recognize that payment for enhanced performance should only be made if
there is a material need for that performance.\83\ Duke agrees, stating
that no study has been conducted that indicates faster response is
necessary for reliable system operations.\84\ While CAISO notes that it
is considering development of a performance payment for regulation
service, it cautions the Commission against requiring a specific
performance payment absent a conclusion that faster-ramping resources
are required in all markets.\85\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\82\ EPSA May 2, 2011 Comments at 7.
\83\ Id. at 6.
\84\ Duke May 2, 2011 Comments at 2.
\85\ CAISO May 2, 2011 Comments at 11-12.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
52. Jack Ellis contends that the Commission's proposal to require a
payment for performance has several flaws that cannot be easily
corrected.\86\ He argues that the first flaw is that the rate is likely
to be administratively-determined. Mr. Ellis contends that there is no
straightforward way for both the mileage payment and the capacity
payment to be established through competitive offers. Therefore, he
argues, the subjective judgment of the Commission and the operators of
RTOs and ISOs will replace market forces in determining the value of
frequency regulation service. Second, Mr. Ellis argues that because the
rate will be administratively-determined, it will be controversial and
subject to litigation. Third, Mr. Ellis contends that the performance
payment will increase payments that must be recovered through uplift,
complicating existing settlement procedures and efforts to reduce
uplift. Fourth, Mr. Ellis argues that a performance payment will unduly
discriminate against existing technologies that could respond faster
but for the presence of barriers that have not, to date, presented
themselves as obstacles. He explains that these barriers include the
use of static ramp rates that reflect typical performance under all
conditions rather than peak performance under conditions that exist at
a point in time. Finally, Mr. Ellis contends that multi-part offers
require complex rules to deter market manipulation because it is
difficult to differentiate between legitimate and illegitimate bidding
behavior.\87\ Mr. Ellis asserts that it is neither reasonable nor cost-
effective to pay a premium for faster ramping capability in situations
where adequate ramping capability is available to meet the grid
operator's needs.\88\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\86\ Jack Ellis April 12, 2011 Comments at 2.
\87\ Jack Ellis April 12, 2011 Comments at 2-3.
\88\ Id. at 3.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
53. TAPS recommends that the Commission direct each of the affected
regions to evaluate its own frequency regulation market rules, and
change them only if they make a regionally-
[[Page 67267]]
specific showing that the changes will increase consumer welfare.\89\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\89\ TAPS May 2, 2011 Comments at 2-3.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
54. Some commenters dispute the position that the integration of
more faster-responding resources for frequency regulation service will
result in lower costs to consumers. Jack Ellis argues that, while it is
possible that RTOs and ISOs could reduce the short-term cost of serving
load by procuring less regulation, long-term costs would likely
increase as supply resources that are pushed out of the frequency
regulation market demand higher prices in other joint product markets
such as capacity, energy, and other ancillary services markets. Mr.
Ellis argues that this will happen because these resources will be
losing revenue and will make up for that lost revenue by bidding in at
higher levels