United States v. Morgan Stanley; Proposed Final Judgment and Competitive Impact Statement, 62843-62850 [2011-26161]
Download as PDF
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 196 / Tuesday, October 11, 2011 / Notices
Commission, U.S. International Trade
Commission, 500 E Street, SW.,
Washington, DC 20436, telephone (202)
205–2000. The public version of the
complaint can be accessed on the
Commission’s electronic docket (EDIS)
at https://edis.usitc.gov, and will be
available for inspection during official
business hours (8:45 a.m. to 5:15 p.m.)
in the Office of the Secretary, U.S.
International Trade Commission, 500 E
Street, SW., Washington, DC 20436,
telephone (202) 205–2000.
General information concerning the
Commission may also be obtained by
accessing its Internet server (https://
www.usitc.gov). The public record for
this investigation may be viewed on the
Commission’s electronic docket (EDIS)
at https://edis.usitc.gov. Hearingimpaired persons are advised that
information on this matter can be
obtained by contacting the
Commission’s TDD terminal on (202)
205–1810.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: The
Commission has received a complaint
filed on behalf of Westinghouse Solar,
Inc. on October 4, 2011. The complaint
alleges violations of section 337 of the
Tariff Act of 1930 (19 U.S.C. 1337) in
the importation into the United States,
the sale for importation, and the sale
within the United States after
importation of certain integrated solar
systems and components thereof. The
complaint names as respondents Zep
Solar, Inc. of CA; Canadian Solar Inc. of
Canada; and Canadian Solar (USA) Inc.
of CA.
The complainant, proposed
respondents, other interested parties,
and members of the public are invited
to file comments, not to exceed five
pages in length, on any public interest
issues raised by the complaint.
Comments should address whether
issuance of an exclusion order and/or a
cease and desist order in this
investigation would negatively affect the
public health and welfare in the United
States, competitive conditions in the
United States economy, the production
of like or directly competitive articles in
the United States, or United States
consumers.
In particular, the Commission is
interested in comments that:
(i) Explain how the articles
potentially subject to the orders are used
in the United States;
(ii) Identify any public health, safety,
or welfare concerns in the United States
relating to the potential orders;
(iii) Indicate the extent to which like
or directly competitive articles are
produced in the United States or are
otherwise available in the United States,
VerDate Mar<15>2010
20:47 Oct 07, 2011
Jkt 226001
with respect to the articles potentially
subject to the orders; and
(iv) Indicate whether Complainant,
Complainant’s licensees, and/or third
party suppliers have the capacity to
replace the volume of articles
potentially subject to an exclusion order
and a cease and desist order within a
commercially reasonable time.
Written submissions must be filed no
later than by close of business, five
business days after the date of
publication of this notice in the Federal
Register. There will be further
opportunities for comment on the
public interest after the issuance of any
final initial determination in this
investigation.
Persons filing written submissions
must file the original document and 12
true copies thereof on or before the
deadlines stated above with the Office
of the Secretary. Submissions should
refer to the docket number (‘‘Docket No.
2847’’) in a prominent place on the
cover page and/or the first page. The
Commission’s rules authorize filing
submissions with the Secretary by
facsimile or electronic means only to the
extent permitted by section 201.8 of the
rules (see Handbook for Electronic
Filing Procedures, https://www.usitc.gov/
secretary/fed_reg_notices/rules/
documents/handbook_on_electronic_
filing.pdf ). Persons with questions
regarding electronic filing should
contact the Secretary (202–205–2000).
Any person desiring to submit a
document to the Commission in
confidence must request confidential
treatment. All such requests should be
directed to the Secretary to the
Commission and must include a full
statement of the reasons why the
Commission should grant such
treatment. See 19 CFR 201.6. Documents
for which confidential treatment by the
Commission is properly sought will be
treated accordingly. All nonconfidential
written submissions will be available for
public inspection at the Office of the
Secretary.
This action is taken under the
authority of section 337 of the Tariff Act
of 1930, as amended (19 U.S.C. 1337),
and of sections 201.10 and 210.50(a)(4)
of the Commission’s Rules of Practice
and Procedure (19 CFR 201.10,
210.50(a)(4)).
By order of the Commission.
Issued: October 4, 2011.
James R. Holbein,
Secretary to the Commission.
[FR Doc. 2011–26097 Filed 10–7–11; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 7020–02–P
PO 00000
Frm 00089
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
62843
INTERNATIONAL TRADE
COMMISSION
[Investigation Nos. 701–TA–318 and 731–
TA–538 and 561 (Third Review)]
Sulfanilic Acid From China and India
Determination
On the basis of the record 1 developed
in the subject five-year reviews, the
United States International Trade
Commission (Commission) determines,
pursuant to section 751(c) of the Tariff
Act of 1930 (19 U.S.C. § 1675(c)), that
revocation of the countervailing duty
order on sulfanilic acid from India and
antidumping duty orders on sulfanilic
acid from China and India would be
likely to lead to continuation or
recurrence of material injury to an
industry in the United States within a
reasonably foreseeable time.
Background
The Commission instituted these
reviews on April 1, 2011 (76 FR 18248)
and determined on July 5, 2011 that it
would conduct expedited reviews (76
FR 50756, August 16, 2011).
The Commission transmitted its
determination in these reviews to the
Secretary of Commerce on October 4,
2011. The views of the Commission are
contained in USITC Publication 4270
(October 2011), entitled Sulfanilic Acid
From China and India: Investigation
Nos. 701–TA–318 and 731–TA–538 and
561 (Third Review).
By order of the Commission.
Issued: October 4, 2011.
James R. Holbein,
Secretary to the Commission.
[FR Doc. 2011–26114 Filed 10–7–11; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 7020–02–P
DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE
Antitrust Division
United States v. Morgan Stanley;
Proposed Final Judgment and
Competitive Impact Statement
Notice is hereby given pursuant to the
Antitrust Procedures and Penalties Act,
15 U.S.C. 16(b)–(h), that a proposed
Final Judgment, Stipulation and
Competitive Impact Statement have
been filed with the United States
District Court for the Southern District
of New York in United States of
America v. Morgan Stanley, Civil Action
No. 11–Civ–6875. On September 30,
2011, the United States filed a
1 The record is defined in sec. 207.2(f) of the Com
mission’s Rules of Practice and Procedure (19 CFR
207.2(f)).
E:\FR\FM\11OCN1.SGM
11OCN1
62844
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 196 / Tuesday, October 11, 2011 / Notices
Complaint alleging that a subsidiary of
Morgan Stanley entered into an
agreement with KeySpan Corporation,
the likely effect of which was to
increase prices in the New York City
(NYISO Zone J) Capacity Market, in
violation of Section 1 of the Sherman
Act, 15 U.S.C. 1. The proposed Final
Judgment, submitted at the same time as
the Complaint, requires Morgan Stanley
to pay the government $4.8 million
dollars.
Copies of the Complaint, proposed
Final Judgment and Competitive Impact
Statement are available for inspection at
the Department of Justice, Antitrust
Division, Antitrust Documents Group,
450 Fifth Street NW., DC 20530 Suite
1010 (telephone: 202–514–2481), on the
Department of Justice’s Web site at
https://www.justice.gov/atr, and at the
Office of the Clerk of the United States
District Court for the Southern District
of New York. Copies of these materials
may be obtained from the Antitrust
Division upon request and payment of
the copying fee set by Department of
Justice regulations.
Public comment is invited within 60
days of the date of this notice. Such
comments, and responses thereto, will
be published in the Federal Register
and filed with the Court. Comments
should be directed to William H.
Stallings, Chief, Transportation Energy
and Agriculture Section, Antitrust
Division, Department of Justice,
Washington, DC 20530, (telephone:
202–514–9323).
Patricia A. Brink,
Director of Civil Enforcement.
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
United States District Court for the
Southern District of New York
United States of America, U.S.
Department of Justice, Antitrust
Division, 450 5th Street, NW., Suite
8000, Washington, DC 20530,
Plaintiff,
v.
Morgan Stanley, 1585 Broadway, New
York, N.Y. 10036, Defendant.
Civil Action No.: 11-civ-6875.
Complaint
The United States of America, acting
under the direction of the Attorney
General of the United States, brings this
civil antitrust action under Section 4 of
the Sherman Act, as amended, 15 U.S.C.
4, to obtain equitable and other relief
from Defendant’s violation of Section 1
of the Sherman Act, as amended, 15
U.S.C. 1.
On January 18, 2006, KeySpan
Corporation (‘‘KeySpan’’) and Morgan
Stanley Capital Group Inc. (‘‘MSGC’’), a
subsidiary of defendant Morgan
VerDate Mar<15>2010
20:47 Oct 07, 2011
Jkt 226001
Stanley,1 executed an agreement (the
‘‘Morgan/KeySpan Swap’’) that ensured
that KeySpan would withhold
substantial output from the New York
City electricity generating capacity
market, a market that was created to
ensure the supply of sufficient
generation capacity for New York City
consumers of electricity. The likely
effect of the Morgan/KeySpan Swap was
to increase capacity prices for the retail
electricity suppliers who must purchase
capacity, and, in turn, to increase the
prices consumers pay for electricity. For
its part, Morgan enjoyed profits arising
from revenues earned in connection
with the Morgan/KeySpan Swap.
I. Introduction
1. Between 2003 and 2006, KeySpan,
the largest seller of electricity generating
capacity (‘‘installed capacity’’) in the
New York City market, earned
substantial revenues due to tight supply
conditions. Because purchasers of
capacity required almost all of
KeySpan’s output to meet expected
demand, KeySpan’s ability to set price
levels was limited only by a regulatory
ceiling (called a ‘‘bid cap’’). Indeed, the
market price for capacity was
consistently at or near KeySpan’s bid
cap, with KeySpan sacrificing sales on
only a small fraction of its capacity.
2. But market conditions were about
to change. Two large, new electricity
generation plants were slated to come
on line in 2006 (with no exit expected
until at least 2009), breaking the
capacity shortage that had kept prices at
the capped levels.
3. KeySpan could prevent the new
capacity from lowering prices by
withholding a substantial amount of its
own capacity from the market. This ‘‘bid
the cap’’ strategy would keep market
prices high, but at a significant cost—
the sacrificed sales would reduce
KeySpan’s revenues by as much as $90
million per year. Alternatively, KeySpan
could compete with its rivals for sales
by bidding more capacity at lower
prices. This ‘‘competitive strategy’’
could earn KeySpan more than bidding
its cap, but it carried a risk—KeySpan’s
competitors could undercut its price
and take sales away, making the strategy
less profitable than ‘‘bidding the cap.’’
4. KeySpan searched for a way to
avoid both the revenue decline from
bidding its cap and the revenue risks of
competitive bidding. It decided to enter
into an agreement that gave it a financial
interest in the capacity of Astoria—
KeySpan’s largest competitor. By
providing KeySpan revenues on a larger
1 MSCG and Morgan Stanley are collectively
referred to hereinafter as ‘‘Morgan.’’
PO 00000
Frm 00090
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
base of sales, such an agreement would
make KeySpan’s ‘‘bid the cap’’ strategy
more profitable than a successful
competitive bid strategy. Rather than
directly approach its competitor,
KeySpan turned to Morgan to act as the
counterparty to the agreement—the
Morgan/KeySpan Swap—recognizing
that Morgan would, and in fact did,
enter into an offsetting agreement with
Astoria (the ‘‘Morgan/Astoria Hedge’’).
5. Morgan recognized that it could
profit from combining the economic
interests of KeySpan and Astoria.
Morgan extracted revenues by entering
into the financial instruments and
thereby stepping into the middle of the
two companies. With KeySpan deriving
revenues from both its own and
Astoria’s capacity, the Morgan/KeySpan
Swap removed any incentive for
KeySpan to bid competitively, locking it
into bidding its cap. Capacity prices
remained as high as if no entry had
occurred.
II. Defendant
6. Morgan Stanley is a Delaware
corporation with its principal place of
business in New York City. Morgan
Stanley provides diversified financial
services, operating a global asset
management business, investment
banking services, and a global securities
business, including a commodities
trading division. Morgan Stanley Capital
Group, Inc., a wholly owned subsidiary
of Morgan Stanley, functions as and is
publicly referred to as the commodities
trading division for the parent company
Morgan Stanley. In 2010, Morgan
Stanley had revenues of $31.6 billion.
III. Jurisdiction and Venue
7. The United States files this
complaint under Section 4 of the
Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. 4, seeking
equitable relief from Defendant’s
violation of Section 1 of the Sherman
Act, 15 U.S.C. 1.
8. This court has jurisdiction over this
matter pursuant to 15 U.S.C. 4 and 28
U.S.C. 1331 and 1337.
9. Defendant waives any objection to
venue and personal jurisdiction in this
judicial district for the purpose of this
Complaint.
10. Defendant engaged in interstate
commerce during the relevant period of
the allegations in this Complaint;
Morgan is a worldwide company that
regularly engages in financial
transactions across the country and
throughout the world.
IV. The New York City Installed
Capacity Market
11. Sellers of retail electricity must
purchase a product from generators
E:\FR\FM\11OCN1.SGM
11OCN1
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 196 / Tuesday, October 11, 2011 / Notices
known as ‘‘installed capacity.’’ Installed
capacity is a product created by the New
York Independent System Operator
(‘‘NYISO’’) to ensure that sufficient
generation capacity exists to meet
expected electricity needs. Companies
selling electricity to consumers in New
York City are required to make installed
capacity payments that relate to their
expected peak demand plus a share of
reserve capacity (to cover extra facilities
needed in case a generating facility
breaks down). These payments assure
that retail electric companies do not sell
more electricity than the system can
deliver and also encourage electric
generating companies to build new
facilities as needed.
12. The price for installed capacity
has been set through auctions
administered by the NYISO. The rules
under which these auctions are
conducted have changed from time to
time. Unless otherwise noted, the
description of the installed capacity
market in the following paragraphs
relates to the period May 2003 through
March 2008.
13. Because transmission constraints
limit the amount of energy that can be
imported into the New York City area
from the power grid, the NYISO requires
retail providers of electricity to
customers in New York City to purchase
80% of their capacity from generators in
that region. The NYISO operates
separate capacity auctions for the New
York City region (also known as ‘‘InCity’’ and ‘‘Zone J’’). The NYISO
organizes the auctions to serve two
distinct seasonal periods, summer (May
through October) and winter (November
through April). For each season, the
NYISO conducts seasonal, monthly and
spot auctions in which capacity can be
acquired for all or some of the seasonal
period.
14. In each of the types of auctions,
capacity suppliers offer price and
quantity bids. Supplier bids are
‘‘stacked’’ from lowest-priced to highest,
and compared to the total amount of
demand being satisfied in the auction.
The offering price of the last bid in the
‘‘stack’’ needed to meet requisite
demand establishes the market price for
all capacity bid into that auction.
Capacity bid at higher than this price is
unsold, as is any excess capacity bid at
what becomes the market price.
15. The New York City Installed
Capacity (‘‘NYC Capacity’’) Market
constitutes a relevant geographic and
product market.
16. The NYC Capacity Market is
highly concentrated, with three firms—
KeySpan, NRG Energy, Inc. (‘‘NRG’’)
and Astoria Generating Company
Acquisitions, L.L.C. (a joint venture of
VerDate Mar<15>2010
20:47 Oct 07, 2011
Jkt 226001
Madison Dearborn Partners, LLC and US
Power Generating Company, which
purchased the Astoria generating assets
from Reliant Energy, Inc. in February
2006)—controlling a substantial portion
of generating capacity in the market.
Because purchasers of capacity require
at least some of each of these three
suppliers’ output to meet expected
demand, the firms are subject to a bid
and price cap for nearly all of their
generating capacity in New York City
and are not allowed to sell that capacity
outside of the NYISO auction process.
The NYISO-set bid cap for KeySpan is
the highest of the three firms, followed
by NRG and Astoria.
17. KeySpan possessed market power
in the NYC Capacity Market.
18. It is difficult and time-consuming
to build or expand generating facilities
within the NYC Capacity Market given
limited undeveloped space for building
or expanding generating facilities and
extensive regulatory obligations.
V. Keyspan’s Plan To Avoid
Competition
19. From June 2003 through December
2005, KeySpan set the market price in
the New York City spot auction by
bidding its capacity at its cap. Given
extremely tight supply and demand
conditions, KeySpan needed to
withhold only a small amount of
capacity to ensure that the market
cleared at its cap.
20. KeySpan anticipated that the tight
supply and demand conditions in the
NYC Capacity Market would change in
2006, due to the entry of approximately
1000 MW of new generation. Because of
the addition of this new capacity,
KeySpan would have to withhold
significantly more capacity from the
market and would earn substantially
lower revenues if it continued to bid all
of its capacity at its bid cap. KeySpan
anticipated that demand growth and
retirement of old generation units would
restore tight supply and demand
conditions in 2009.
21. KeySpan could no longer be
confident that ‘‘bidding the cap’’ would
remain its best strategy during the 2006–
2009 period. It considered various
competitive bidding strategies under
which KeySpan would compete with its
rivals for sales by bidding more capacity
at lower prices. These strategies could
potentially produce much higher
returns for KeySpan but carried the risk
that competitors would undercut its
price and take sales away, making the
strategy less profitable than ‘‘bidding
the cap.’’
22. KeySpan also considered
acquiring Astoria’s generating assets,
which were for sale. This would have
PO 00000
Frm 00091
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
62845
solved the problem that new entry
posed for KeySpan’s revenue stream, as
Astoria’s capacity would have provided
KeySpan with sufficient additional
revenues to make continuing to ‘‘bid the
cap’’ its best strategy. KeySpan
consulted with Morgan about acquiring
the assets. But KeySpan soon concluded
that its acquisition of its largest
competitor would raise serious market
power issues and communicated that
conclusion to Morgan.
23. Instead of purchasing the Astoria
assets, KeySpan decided to acquire a
financial interest in substantially all of
Astoria’s capacity. KeySpan would pay
Astoria’s owner a fixed revenue stream
in return for the revenues generated
from Astoria’s capacity sales in the
auctions.
24. KeySpan did not approach Astoria
directly, instead approaching Morgan to
arrange a financial agreement providing
KeySpan with payments derived from
the market clearing price for an amount
of capacity essentially equivalent to
what Astoria owned. KeySpan
recognized that Morgan would need
simultaneously to enter into an offsetting financial agreement with another
capacity supplier. Morgan agreed to
such a Swap but, as expected, informed
KeySpan that the agreement was
contingent on Morgan entering into an
offsetting agreement with the owner of
the Astoria assets.
VI. Morgan’s Agreements With Keyspan
and Astoria
25. Over the course of late 2005,
Morgan negotiated the terms of the
derivative agreements with Astoria and
KeySpan. Those negotiations illustrate
that Morgan recognized its role as a
principal in effectively combining the
capacity of the two companies. Under
the terms initially discussed with
Astoria, Morgan would have controlled
the bidding of Astoria’s capacity.
Morgan also proposed that the financial
derivative with Astoria be converted
into a physical contract, transferring the
rights to Astoria’s capacity to Morgan in
exchange for fixed payments, in the
event that the structure of the auction
market was disrupted; and, at the same
time, Morgan proposed in its
negotiations with KeySpan to transfer
this physical capacity to KeySpan
should a market disruption occur.
26. On or about January 9, 2006,
KeySpan and Morgan finalized the
terms of the Morgan/KeySpan Swap.
Under the agreement, if the market price
for capacity was above $7.57 per kWmonth, Morgan would pay KeySpan the
difference between the market price and
$7.57 times 1800 MW; if the market
price was below $7.57, KeySpan would
E:\FR\FM\11OCN1.SGM
11OCN1
62846
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 196 / Tuesday, October 11, 2011 / Notices
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
pay Morgan the difference times 1800
MW.
27. The Morgan/KeySpan Swap was
executed on January 18, 2006. The term
of the Morgan/KeySpan Swap ran from
May 2006 through April 2009.
28. On or about January 9, 2006,
Morgan and Astoria finalized the terms
of the Morgan/Astoria Hedge. Under
that agreement, if the market price for
capacity was above $7.07 per kWmonth, Astoria would pay Morgan the
difference times 1800 MW; if the market
price was below $7.07, Astoria would be
paid the difference times 1800 MW.
29. The Morgan/Astoria Hedge was
executed on January 11, 2006. The term
of the Morgan/Astoria Hedge ran from
May 2006 through April 2009, matching
the duration of the Morgan/KeySpan
Swap.
VII. The Competitive Effect of the
Morgan/Keyspan Swap
30. The clear tendency of the Morgan/
KeySpan Swap was to alter KeySpan’s
bidding in the NYC Capacity Market
auctions.
31. Without the Morgan/KeySpan
Swap, KeySpan likely would have
chosen from a range of potentially
profitable competitive strategies in
response to the entry of new capacity.
Had it done so, the price of capacity
would have declined. By transferring a
financial interest in Astoria’s capacity to
KeySpan, however, the Morgan/
KeySpan Swap effectively eliminated
KeySpan’s incentive to compete for
sales in the same way a purchase of
Astoria or a direct agreement between
KeySpan and Astoria would have done.
By providing KeySpan revenues from
Astoria’s capacity, in addition to
KeySpan’s own revenues, the Morgan/
KeySpan Swap made bidding the cap
KeySpan’s most profitable strategy
regardless of its rivals’ bids.
32. After the Morgan/KeySpan Swap
went into effect in May 2006, KeySpan
paid and received revenues under the
agreement with Morgan and
consistently bid its capacity at its cap
even though a significant portion of its
capacity went unsold. Despite the
addition of significant new generating
capacity in New York City, the market
price of capacity did not decline.
33. In August 2007, the State of New
York conditioned the sale of KeySpan to
a new owner on the divestiture of
KeySpan’s Ravenswood generating
assets and required KeySpan to bid its
New York City capacity at zero from
March 2008 until the divestiture was
completed. Since March 2008, the
market price for capacity has declined.
34. But for the Morgan/KeySpan
Swap, installed capacity likely would
VerDate Mar<15>2010
20:47 Oct 07, 2011
Jkt 226001
have been procured at a lower price in
New York City from May 2006 through
February 2008.
35. From May 2006 to April 2008,
Morgan earned approximately $21.6
million in net revenues from the
Morgan/KeySpan Swap and the
Morgan/Astoria Hedge.
36. The Morgan/KeySpan Swap
produced no countervailing efficiencies.
Competitive Impact Statement
Plaintiff United States of America
(‘‘United States’’), pursuant to Section
2(b) of the Antitrust Procedures and
Penalties Act (‘‘APPA’’ or ‘‘Tunney
Act’’), 15 U.S.C. 16(b)-(h), files this
Competitive Impact Statement relating
to the proposed Final Judgment
submitted for entry in this civil antitrust
proceeding.
VIII. Violation Alleged
I. Nature and Purpose of the
Proceedings
The United States brought this
lawsuit against Defendant Morgan
Stanley (‘‘Morgan’’) on September 30,
2011, to remedy a violation of Section
1 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. 1. In
January 2006, Morgan Stanley Capital
Group Inc. (‘‘MSGC’’), a subsidiary of
defendant Morgan Stanley,2executed
agreements with KeySpan Corporation
(‘‘KeySpan’’) and Astoria Generating
Company Acquisitions, L.L.C.
(‘‘Astoria’’) that would effectively
combine the economic interests of the
two largest competitors in the New York
City electric capacity market. By
creating this combination, the likely
effect of the agreements was to increase
capacity prices for the retail electricity
suppliers who must purchase capacity,
and, in turn, to increase the prices
consumers pay for electricity.
The proposed Final Judgment
remedies this violation by requiring
Morgan to disgorge profits obtained
through the anticompetitive agreement.
Under the terms of the proposed Final
Judgment, Morgan will surrender $4.8
million to the Treasury of the United
States. Disgorgement will deter Morgan
and others from future violations of the
antitrust laws.
The United States and Morgan have
stipulated that the proposed Final
Judgment may be entered after
compliance with the APPA, unless the
United States withdraws its consent.
Entry of the proposed Final Judgment
would terminate this action, except that
this Court would retain jurisdiction to
construe, modify, and enforce the
proposed Final Judgment and to punish
violations thereof.
37. Plaintiff incorporates the
allegations of paragraphs 1 through 36
above.
38. Morgan entered into an agreement
the likely effect of which has been to
increase prices in the NYC Capacity
Market, in violation of Section 1 of the
Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. 1.
IX. Prayer for Relief
Wherefore, Plaintiff prays:
39. That the Court adjudge and decree
that the Morgan/KeySpan Swap
constitutes an illegal restraint in the sale
of installed capacity in the New York
City market in violation of Section 1 of
the Sherman Act;
40. That Plaintiff shall have such
other relief, including equitable
monetary relief, as the nature of this
case may require and as is just and
proper to prevent the recurrence of the
alleged violation and to dissipate the
anticompetitive effects of the violation;
and
41. That Plaintiff recover the costs of
this action.
Dated: September 30, 2011.
Respectfully submitted,
For Plaintiff United States.
Sharis A. Pozen,
Acting Assistant Attorney General for
Antitrust.
Joseph F. Wayland,
Deputy Assistant Attorney General.
Patricia A. Brink,
Director of Civil Enforcement.
Wlliam H. Stallings,
Chief, Transportation, Energy & Agriculture
Section.
Jade Eaton,
Attorney, Transportation, Energy &
Agriculture Section, Antitrust Division,
U.S. Department of Justice, 450 Fifth
Street, NW., Suite 8000, Washington, DC
20530, Telephone: (202) 353–1560,
Facsimile: (202) 616–2441, e-mail:
jade.eaton@usdoj.gov.
J. Richard Doidge,
John W. Elias, Attorneys for the United
States.
United States of America, Plaintiff,
v.
Morgan Stanley, Defendant.
Civil Action No.: 11–civ–6875.
PO 00000
Frm 00092
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
II. Description of the Events Giving Rise
to the Alleged Violation of the Antitrust
Laws
A. The Defendant
Morgan Stanley is a Delaware
corporation with its principal place of
business in New York City. Morgan
Stanley provides diversified financial
services, operating a global asset
2 MSCG and Morgan Stanley are collectively
referred to hereinafter as ‘‘Morgan.’’
E:\FR\FM\11OCN1.SGM
11OCN1
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 196 / Tuesday, October 11, 2011 / Notices
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
management business, investment
banking services, and a global securities
business, including a commodities
trading division. In 2010, Morgan
Stanley had revenues of $31.6 billion.
Morgan Stanley Capital Group, Inc., a
wholly owned subsidiary of Morgan
Stanley, functions as and is publicly
referred to as the commodities trading
division for the parent company Morgan
Stanley.
B. The Market
In the state of New York, sellers of
retail electricity must purchase a
product from generators known as
installed capacity (‘‘capacity’’).3
Electricity retailers are required to
purchase capacity in an amount equal to
their expected peak energy demand plus
a share of reserve capacity. These
payments assure that retail electric
companies do not use more electricity
than the system can deliver and
encourage electric generating companies
to build new facilities as needed.
Because transmission constraints limit
the amount of energy that can be
imported into the New York City area
from the power grid, the New York
Independent System Operator
(‘‘NYISO’’) requires retail providers of
electricity to customers in New York
City to purchase 80% of their capacity
from generators in that region. Thus, the
New York City Installed Capacity (‘‘NYC
Capacity’’) Market constitutes a relevant
geographic and product market.
The price for installed capacity has
been set through auctions administered
by the NYISO. The NYISO organizes the
auctions to serve two distinct seasonal
periods, summer (May though October)
and winter (November through April).
For each season, the NYISO conducts
seasonal, monthly, and spot auctions in
which capacity can be acquired for all
or some of the seasonal period. Capacity
suppliers offer price and quantity bids
in each of these three auctions. Supplier
bids are ‘‘stacked’’ from lowest-priced to
highest. The stack is then compared to
the amount of demand. The offering
price of the last bid in the ‘‘stack’’
needed to meet requisite demand
establishes the market price for all
capacity sold into that auction. Any
capacity bid at higher than this price is
unsold, as is any excess capacity bid at
what becomes the market price.
The NYC Capacity Market was highly
concentrated during the relevant period,
with three firms—Astoria, NRG Energy,
Inc., and KeySpan—controlling a
substantial portion of the market’s
3 Except where noted otherwise, this description
pertains to the market conditions that existed from
May 2003 through March 2008.
VerDate Mar<15>2010
20:47 Oct 07, 2011
Jkt 226001
generating capacity. These three were
designated as pivotal suppliers by the
Federal Energy Regulatory Commission,
meaning that at least some of each of
these three suppliers’ output was
required to satisfy demand. The three
firms were subject to bid and price
caps—KeySpan’s being the highest—for
nearly all of their generating capacity in
New York City and were not allowed to
sell their capacity outside of the NYISO
auction process.
C. The Alleged Violation
1. KeySpan Assesses Plans for
Changed Market Conditions
From June 2003 through December
2005, almost all installed capacity in the
market was needed to meet demand.
With these tight market conditions,
KeySpan could sell almost all of its
capacity into the market, even while
bidding at its cap. KeySpan did so, and
the market cleared at the price
established by the cap, with only a
small fraction of KeySpan’s capacity
remaining unsold.
KeySpan anticipated that the tight
supply and demand conditions in the
NYC Capacity Market would end in
2006 due to the entry into the market of
approximately 1000 MW of generation
capacity, and would not return until
2009 with the retirement of old
generation units and demand growth.
KeySpan could no longer be confident
that ‘‘bid the cap’’ would remain its best
strategy during the 2006–2009 period.
The ‘‘bid the cap’’ strategy would keep
market prices high, but at a significant
cost. KeySpan would have to withhold
a significant additional amount of
capacity to account for the new entry.
The additional withholding would
reduce KeySpan’s revenues by as much
as $90 million per year. Alternatively,
KeySpan could compete with its rivals
for sales by bidding more capacity at
lower prices. KeySpan considered
various competitive bidding strategies.
These could potentially produce much
higher returns for KeySpan than bidding
the cap but carried the risk that
competitors would undercut its price
and take sales away, making the strategy
potentially less profitable than bidding
the cap.
KeySpan also considered acquiring
Astoria’s generating assets from Reliant
Energy, Inc., which was putting them up
for sale. This would have solved the
problem that new entry posed for
KeySpan’s revenue stream, as Astoria’s
capacity would have provided KeySpan
with sufficient additional revenues to
make continuing to ‘‘bid the cap’’ its
best strategy. Simultaneously, Morgan
was interested in buying the same assets
and seeking a strategic partner with
PO 00000
Frm 00093
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
62847
whom to bid. Morgan and KeySpan
discussed such a partnership and the
market power issues of a bid involving
KeySpan. KeySpan soon concluded that
its acquisition of its largest competitor
would raise serious market power issues
and communicated that conclusion to
Morgan.
2. Morgan Facilitates the
Anticompetitive and Unlawful
Agreement
Instead of purchasing the Astoria
assets, KeySpan decided to acquire a
financial interest in substantially all of
Astoria’s capacity. KeySpan would pay
Astoria’s owner a fixed revenue stream
in return for the revenues generated
from Astoria’s capacity sales in the
auctions.
KeySpan realized that it could not
approach the owner of Astoria assets
directly, so it turned to Morgan to act as
a counter-party. Morgan agreed to serve
as the counter-party but informed
KeySpan that the agreement was
contingent on it entering into an
offsetting agreement with the owner of
the Astoria generating assets.
On or about January 9, 2006, KeySpan
and Morgan finalized the terms of a
financial derivative arrangement
between the two companies, ‘‘the
Morgan/KeySpan Swap.’’ Under the
agreement, if the market price for
capacity was above $7.57 per kWmonth, Morgan would pay KeySpan the
difference between the market price and
$7.57 times 1800 MW; if the market
price was below $7.57, KeySpan would
pay Morgan the difference times 1800
MW. The Morgan/KeySpan Swap was
executed on January 18, 2006. The term
of the Morgan/KeySpan Swap ran from
May 2006 through April 2009.
On or about January 9, 2006, Morgan
and Astoria finalized the terms of the
offsetting agreement (‘‘Morgan/Astoria
Hedge’’). Under that agreement, if the
market price for capacity was above
$7.07 per kW-month, Astoria would pay
Morgan the difference times 1800 MW;
if the market price was below $7.07,
Astoria would be paid the difference
times 1800 MW. The Morgan/Astoria
Hedge was executed on January 11,
2006. The term of the Morgan/Astoria
Hedge ran from May 2006 through April
2009, matching the duration of the
Morgan/KeySpan Swap.
Morgan earned approximately $21.6
million in net revenues from the
Morgan/KeySpan Swap and the
Morgan/Astoria Hedge.
3. The Effect of the Morgan/KeySpan
Swap
After the Morgan/KeySpan Swap
went into effect in May 2006, KeySpan
E:\FR\FM\11OCN1.SGM
11OCN1
62848
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 196 / Tuesday, October 11, 2011 / Notices
consistently bid its capacity into the
capacity auctions at its cap even though
a significant portion of its capacity went
unsold. Despite the addition of
significant new generating capacity in
New York City, the market price of
capacity did not decline.
The clear tendency of the Morgan/
KeySpan Swap was to alter KeySpan’s
bidding in the NYC Capacity Market
auctions. The swap effectively
eliminated KeySpan’s incentive to
compete for sales in the same way a
purchase of Astoria or a direct
agreement between KeySpan and
Astoria would have done. By adding
revenues from Astoria’s capacity to
KeySpan’s own, the Morgan/KeySpan
Swap made bidding the cap KeySpan’s
most profitable strategy regardless of its
rivals’ bids. Without the swap, KeySpan
likely would have chosen from a range
of potentially profitable competitive
strategies in response to the entry of
new capacity and, had it done so, the
price of capacity would have declined.
The swap produced no countervailing
efficiencies.
III. United States v. Keyspan
Corporation
On February 22, 2010, the United
States filed suit against KeySpan for its
role in the Morgan/KeySpan Swap.
Simultaneous with the filing of its
Complaint, the United States filed a
proposed Final Judgment requiring
KeySpan to pay to the United States $12
million as disgorgement of ill-gotten
gains. See Complaint, United States v.
KeySpan Corp., No. 10–1415 (S.D.N.Y.
Feb. 22, 2010). After completion of the
procedures set forth in the Tunney Act,
including public notice and comment,
the United States moved for entry of the
proposed Final Judgment. In the course
of making its public interest
determination, the Court found that
disgorgement is available to remedy
violations of the Sherman Act. See
United States v. KeySpan Corp., 763 F.
Supp. 2d 633, 638–641. The KeySpan
Final Judgment was entered on February
2, 2011.
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
IV. Explanation of the Proposed Final
Judgment
The proposed Final Judgment requires
Morgan to disgorge profits gained as a
result of its unlawful agreement
restraining trade. Morgan is to surrender
$4.8 million to the Treasury of the
United States.
KeySpan, pursuant to a Final
Judgment sought by the United States,
has surrendered $12 million as a result
of its role in the Morgan/KeySpan
VerDate Mar<15>2010
20:47 Oct 07, 2011
Jkt 226001
Swap.4 See United States v. KeySpan
Corp., 763 F. Supp. 2d 633, 637–38
(S.D.N.Y. 2011). Securing similar
disgorgement from the other responsible
party to the anticompetitive agreement
will protect the public interest by
depriving Morgan of a substantial
portion of the fruits of the agreement.
The effect of the swap agreement was to
effectively combine the economic
interests of KeySpan and Astoria,
thereby permitting KeySpan to increase
prices above competitive rates, and this
result could not have been achieved
without Morgan’s participation in the
swap agreement. Requiring
disgorgement in these circumstances
will thus protect the public interest by
deterring Morgan and other parties from
entering into similar financial
agreements that result in
anticompetitive effects in the
underlying markets, or from otherwise
engaging in similar anticompetitive
conduct in the future.
The $4.8 million disgorgement
amount is the product of settlement and
accounts for litigation risks and costs.
While the disgorged sum represents less
than all of Morgan’s net transaction
revenues under the two agreements,5
disgorgement will effectively fulfill the
remedial goals of the Sherman Act to
‘‘prevent and restrain’’ antitrust
violations as it will send a message of
deterrence to those in the financial
services community considering the use
of derivatives for anticompetitive ends.
V. Remedies Available to Potential
Private Litigants
Section 4 of the Clayton Act, 15
U.S.C. 15, provides that any person who
has been injured as a result of conduct
prohibited by the antitrust laws may
bring suit in federal court to recover
three times the damages the person has
suffered, as well as costs and reasonable
attorneys’ fees. Entry of the proposed
Final Judgment will neither impair nor
assist the bringing of any private
antitrust damage action. Under the
4 Had the KeySpan case proceeded to trial, the
United States would have sought disgorgement of
the approximately $49 million in net revenues that
KeySpan received under the Swap, contending that
these net revenues reflected the value that KeySpan
received from trading the uncertainty of competing
for the certainty of the bid-the-cap strategy. See
Plaintiff United States’s Response to Public
Comments at 14–18, United States v. KeySpan
Corp., No. 10–1415 (S.D.N.Y. June 11, 2010).
5 Had the case against Morgan proceeded to trial,
the United States would have sought disgorgement
of the $21.6 million in net transaction revenues
Morgan earned under both the Morgan/KeySpan
Swap and the Morgan/Astoria Hedge. At trial,
Morgan—in addition to raising arguments as to its
lack of liability in general—would have disputed
that the entire $21.6 million earned under both
agreements would be cognizable as ill-gotten gains.
PO 00000
Frm 00094
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
provisions of Section 5(a) of the Clayton
Act, 15 U.S.C. 16(a), the proposed Final
Judgment has no prima facie effect in
any subsequent private lawsuit that may
be brought against Morgan.
VI. Procedures Available for
Modification of the Proposed Final
Judgment
The United States and the Defendant
have stipulated that the proposed Final
Judgment may be entered by the Court
after compliance with the provisions of
the APPA, provided that the United
States has not withdrawn its consent.
The APPA conditions entry upon the
Court’s determination that the proposed
Final Judgment is in the public interest.
The APPA provides a period of at
least sixty (60) days preceding the
effective date of the proposed Final
Judgment within which any person may
submit to the United States written
comments regarding the proposed Final
Judgment. Any person who wishes to
comment should do so within sixty (60)
days of the date of publication of this
Competitive Impact Statement in the
Federal Register, or the last date of
publication in a newspaper of the
summary of this Competitive Impact
Statement, whichever is later. All
comments received during this period
will be considered by the United States,
which remains free to withdraw its
consent to the proposed Final Judgment
at any time prior to the Court’s entry of
judgment. The comments and the
response of the United States will be
filed with the Court and published in
the Federal Register.
Written comments should be
submitted to: William H. Stallings,
Chief, Transportation, Energy &
Agriculture Section, Antitrust Division,
United States Department of Justice, 450
Fifth Street, NW.; Suite 8000,
Washington, DC 20530.
The proposed Final Judgment
provides that the Court retains
jurisdiction over this action, and the
parties may apply to the Court for any
order necessary or appropriate for the
modification, interpretation, or
enforcement of the Final Judgment.
VII. Alternatives to the Proposed Final
Judgment
The United States considered, as an
alternative to the proposed Final
Judgment, a full trial on the merits
against the Defendant. The United
States is satisfied, however, that the
disgorgement of profits is an appropriate
remedy in this matter. A disgorgement
remedy should deter Morgan and others
from engaging in similar conduct and
thus achieves a significant portion of the
relief the United States would have
E:\FR\FM\11OCN1.SGM
11OCN1
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 196 / Tuesday, October 11, 2011 / Notices
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
obtained through litigation but avoids
the time, expense, and uncertainty of
discovery and a full trial on the merits
of the Complaint.
VIII. Standard of Review Under the
APPA for Proposed Final Judgment
The Clayton Act, as amended by the
APPA, requires that proposed consent
judgments in antitrust cases brought by
the United States be subject to a sixtyday comment period, after which the
court shall determine whether entry of
the proposed Final Judgment ‘‘is in the
public interest.’’ 15 U.S.C. 16(e)(1). In
making that determination, the court is
directed to consider:
(A) The competitive impact of such
judgment, including termination of
alleged violations, provisions for
enforcement and modification, duration
of relief sought, anticipated effects of
alternative remedies actually
considered, whether its terms are
ambiguous, and any other competitive
considerations bearing upon the
adequacy of such judgment that the
court deems necessary to a
determination of whether the consent
judgment is in the public interest; and
(B) the impact of entry of such
judgment upon competition in the
relevant market or markets, upon the
public generally and individuals
alleging specific injury from the
violations set forth in the complaint
including consideration of the public
benefit, if any, to be derived from a
determination of the issues at trial.
15 U.S.C. 16(e)(1)(A) & (B); see generally
United States v. KeySpan Corp., 763 F.
Supp. 2d 633, 637–38 (S.D.N.Y. 2011)
(WHP) (discussing Tunney Act
standards); United States v. SBC
Commc’ns, Inc., 489 F. Supp. 2d 1
(D.D.C. 2007) (assessing standards for
public interest determination). In
considering these statutory factors, the
court’s inquiry is necessarily a limited
one as the United States is entitled to
‘‘broad discretion to settle with the
Defendant within the reaches of the
public interest.’’ United States v.
Microsoft Corp., 56 F.3d 1448, 1461
(D.C. Cir. 1995).
Under the APPA a court considers,
among other things, the relationship
between the remedy secured and the
specific allegations set forth in the
United States’ complaint, whether the
decree is sufficiently clear, whether
enforcement mechanisms are sufficient,
and whether the decree may positively
harm third parties. See Microsoft, 56
F.3d at 1458–62. With respect to the
adequacy of the relief secured by the
decree, the court’s function is ‘‘not to
determine whether the proposed
[d]ecree results in the balance of rights
VerDate Mar<15>2010
20:47 Oct 07, 2011
Jkt 226001
and liabilities that is the one that will
best serve society, but only to ensure
that the resulting settlement is within
the reaches of the public interest.’’
KeySpan, 763 F. Supp. 2d at 637
(quoting United States v. Alex Brown &
Sons, Inc., 963 F. Supp. 235, 238
(S.D.N.Y. 1997) (internal quotations
omitted). In making this determination,
‘‘[t]he [c]ourt is not permitted to reject
the proposed remedies merely because
the court believes other remedies are
preferable. [Rather], the relevant inquiry
is whether there is a factual foundation
for the government’s decision such that
its conclusions regarding the proposed
settlement are reasonable.’’ Id. at 637–38
(quoting United States v. Abitibi–
Consolidated Inc., 584 F. Supp. 2d 162,
165 (D.D.C. 2008).6 The government’s
predictions about the efficacy of its
remedies are entitled to deference.7
Courts have greater flexibility in
approving proposed consent decrees
than in crafting their own decrees
following a finding of liability in a
litigated matter. ‘‘[A] proposed decree
must be approved even if it falls short
of the remedy the court would impose
on its own, as long as it falls within the
range of acceptability or is ‘within the
reaches of public interest.’ ’’ United
States v. Am. Tel. & Tel. Co., 552 F.
Supp. 131, 151 (D.D.C. 1982) (citations
omitted) (quoting United States v.
Gillette Co., 406 F. Supp. 713, 716 (D.
Mass. 1975)), aff’d sub nom. Maryland
v. United States, 460 U.S. 1001 (1983);
see also United States v. Alcan
Aluminum Ltd., 605 F. Supp. 619, 622
(W.D. Ky. 1985) (approving the consent
decree even though the court would
have imposed a greater remedy). To
meet this standard, the United States
‘‘need only provide a factual basis for
concluding that the settlements are
reasonably adequate remedies for the
alleged harms.’’ SBC Commc’ns, 489 F.
Supp. 2d at 17.
Moreover, the court’s role under the
APPA is limited to reviewing the
remedy in relationship to the violations
6 United States v. Bechtel Corp., 648 F.2d 660,
666 (9th Cir. 1981) (‘‘The balancing of competing
social and political interests affected by a proposed
antitrust consent decree must be left, in the first
instance, to the discretion of the Attorney
General.’’). See generally Microsoft, 56 F.3d at 1461
(discussing whether ‘‘the remedies [obtained in the
decree are] so inconsonant with the allegations
charged as to fall outside of the ‘reaches of the
public interest’ ’’).
7 Microsoft, 56 F.3d at 1461 (noting the need for
courts to be ‘‘deferential to the government’s
predictions as to the effect of the proposed
remedies’’); United States v. Archer-DanielsMidland Co., 272 F. Supp. 2d 1, 6 (D.D.C. 2003)
(noting that the court should grant due respect to
the United States’ prediction as to the effect of
proposed remedies, its perception of the market
structure, and its views of the nature of the case).
PO 00000
Frm 00095
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
62849
that the United States has alleged in its
Complaint, and does not authorize the
court to ‘‘construct [its] own
hypothetical case and then evaluate the
decree against that case.’’ Microsoft, 56
F.3d at 1459; KeySpan, 763 F. Supp. 2d
at 638 (‘‘A court must limit its review
to the issues in the complaint * * *.’’).
Because the ‘‘court’s authority to review
the decree depends entirely on the
government’s exercising its
prosecutorial discretion by bringing a
case in the first place,’’ it follows that
‘‘the court is only authorized to review
the decree itself,’’ and not to ‘‘effectively
redraft the complaint’’ to inquire into
other matters that the United States did
not pursue. Microsoft, 56 F.3d at 1459–
60.
In its 2004 amendments, Congress
made clear its intent to preserve the
practical benefits of utilizing consent
decrees in antitrust enforcement, adding
the unambiguous instruction that
‘‘[n]othing in this section shall be
construed to require the court to
conduct an evidentiary hearing or to
require the court to permit anyone to
intervene.’’ 15 U.S.C. 16(e)(2). This
language effectuates what Congress
intended when it enacted the Tunney
Act in 1974, as Senator Tunney
explained: ‘‘[t]he court is nowhere
compelled to go to trial or to engage in
extended proceedings which might have
the effect of vitiating the benefits of
prompt and less costly settlement
through the consent decree process.’’
119 Cong. Rec. 24,598 (1973) (statement
of Senator Tunney). Rather, the
procedure for the public interest
determination is left to the discretion of
the court, with the recognition that the
court’s ‘‘scope of review remains
sharply proscribed by precedent and the
nature of Tunney Act proceedings.’’
SBC Commc’ns, 489 F. Supp. 2d at 11.8
IX. Determinative Documents
There are no determinative materials
or documents within the meaning of the
APPA that the United States considered
in formulating the proposed Final
Judgment.
Dated: September 30, 2011.
Respectfully submitted,
For Plaintiff
the United States of America.
Jade Alice Eaton,
Trial Attorney, United States Department of
Justice, Antitrust Division, Transportation,
Energy & Agriculture Section, 450 5th Street,
NW., Suite 8000, Washington, DC 20530,
8 See United States v. Enova Corp., 107 F. Supp.
2d 10, 17 (D.D.C. 2000) (noting that the ‘‘Tunney
Act expressly allows the court to make its public
interest determination on the basis of the
competitive impact statement and response to
comments alone’’).
E:\FR\FM\11OCN1.SGM
11OCN1
62850
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 196 / Tuesday, October 11, 2011 / Notices
Telephone: (202) 307–6316,
jade.eaton@usdoj.gov.
IV. Retention of Jurisdiction
United States of America, Plaintiff,
v.
Morgan Stanley, Defendant.
Civil Action No.
Final Judgment
Whereas Plaintiff United States of
America filed its Complaint alleging
that Defendant Morgan Stanley
(‘‘Morgan’’) violated Section 1 of the
Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. 1, and Plaintiff
and Morgan, through their respective
attorneys, having consented to the entry
of this Final Judgment without trial or
adjudication of any issue of fact or law,
for settlement purposes only, and
without this Final Judgment
constituting any evidence against or an
admission by Morgan for any purpose
with respect to any claim or allegation
contained in the Complaint:
Now, Therefore, before the taking of
any testimony and without trial or
adjudication of any issue of fact or law
herein, and upon the consent of the
parties hereto, it is hereby Ordered,
Adjudged, and Decreed:
I. Jurisdiction
This Court has jurisdiction of the
subject matter herein and of each of the
parties consenting hereto. The
Complaint states a claim upon which
relief may be granted to the United
States against Morgan under Sections 1
and 4 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. 1
and 4.
This Final Judgment applies to
Morgan and each of its successors,
assigns, and to all other persons in
active concert or participation with it
who shall have received actual notice of
the Settlement Agreement and Order by
personal service or otherwise.
mstockstill on DSK4VPTVN1PROD with NOTICES
III. Relief
A. Within thirty (30) days of the entry
of this Final Judgment, Morgan shall
pay to the United States the sum of four
million eight hundred thousand dollars
($4,800,000.00).
B. The payment specified above shall
be made by wire transfer. Before making
the transfer, Morgan shall contact Janie
Ingalls, of the Antitrust Division’s
Antitrust Documents Group, at (202)
514–2481 for wire transfer instructions.
C. In the event of a default in
payment, interest at the rate of eighteen
(18) percent per annum shall accrue
thereon from the date of default to the
date of payment.
20:47 Oct 07, 2011
V. Public Interest Determination
Entry of this Final Judgment is in the
public interest. The parties have
complied with the requirements of the
Antitrust Procedures and Penalties Act,
15 U.S.C. 16, including making copies
available to the public of this Final
Judgment, the Competitive Impact
Statement, and any comments thereon
and Plaintiff’s responses to comments.
Based upon the record before the Court,
which includes the Competitive Impact
Statement and any comments and
response to comments filed with the
Court, entry of this Final Judgment is in
the public interest.
Dated: lllllllllllllll
llllllllllllllllll
l
United States District Judge.
[FR Doc. 2011–26161 Filed 10–7–11; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 4410–11–P
Jaleh F. Barrett,
Chief Counsel.
[FR Doc. 2011–26305 Filed 10–6–11; 4:15 pm]
BILLING CODE 4410–BA–P
DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE
National Institute of Corrections
Advisory Board Meeting
Time and Date: 8 a.m. to 4:30
p.m. on Wednesday, November 2, 2011,
8 a.m. to 4:30 p.m. on Thursday,
November 28, 2011.
PLACE: National Corrections Academy,
11900 East Cornell Avenue, Aurora, CO
80014, 1 (303) 338–6600.
MATTERS TO BE CONSIDERED: Important
trends in corrections-related policy,
program, and practices; identifying and
meeting the needs of the field of
corrections; Performance Based
Outcomes; Director’s report; Federal
Partners Reports; Presentations.
CONTACT PERSON FOR MORE INFORMATION:
Thomas Beauclair, Deputy Director,
202–307–3106, ext. 44254.
DATES:
Morris L. Thigpen,
Director.
[FR Doc. 2011–25880 Filed 10–7–11; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 4410–36–M
DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE
Foreign Claims Settlement
Commission
II. Applicability
VerDate Mar<15>2010
This Court retains jurisdiction to
enable any party to this Final Judgment
to apply to this Court at any time for
further orders and directions as may be
necessary or appropriate to carry out or
construe this Final Judgment, to modify
any of its provisions, to enforce
compliance, and to punish violations of
its provisions. Upon notification by the
United States to the Court of Morgan’s
payment of the funds required by
Section III above, this Section IV will
have no further force or effect.
Executive Officer, Foreign Claims
Settlement Commission, 600 E Street,
NW., Suite 6002, Washington, DC
20579. Telephone: (202) 616–6975.
Jkt 226001
DEPARTMENT OF LABOR
[F.C.S.C. Meeting and Hearing Notice No.
10–11]
Occupational Safety and Health
Administration
Sunshine Act Meeting
[Docket No. OSHA–2010–0018]
The Foreign Claims Settlement
Commission, pursuant to its regulations
(45 CFR part 503.25) and the
Government in the Sunshine Act (5
U.S.C. 552b), hereby gives notice in
regard to the scheduling of open
meetings as follows:
Monday, October 17, 2011: 10:30
a.m.—Issuance of Proposed Decisions in
claims against Libya; 3 p.m.—Oral
hearings on objections to Commission’s
Proposed Decisions in Claim Nos.LIB–
II–128, LIB–II–129, LIB–II–130 and LIB–
II–131.
Status: Open.
All meetings are held at the Foreign
Claims Settlement Commission, 600 E
Street, NW., Washington, DC. Requests
for information, or advance notices of
intention to observe an open meeting,
may be directed to: Judith H. Lock,
Curtis-Straus LLC; Application for
Renewal of Recognition
PO 00000
Frm 00096
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
Occupational Safety and Health
Administration (OSHA), Labor.
ACTION: Notice.
AGENCY:
This notice announces the
application of Curtis-Straus LLC for
renewal of its recognition as a
Nationally Recognized Testing
Laboratory (NRTL) and presents the
Agency’s preliminary finding to deny
this application for renewal of NRTL
recognition.
SUMMARY:
Submit information or
comments, or a request to extend the
comment period, on or before November
10, 2011. All submissions must bear a
postmark or provide other evidence of
the submission date.
DATES:
E:\FR\FM\11OCN1.SGM
11OCN1
Agencies
[Federal Register Volume 76, Number 196 (Tuesday, October 11, 2011)]
[Notices]
[Pages 62843-62850]
From the Federal Register Online via the Government Printing Office [www.gpo.gov]
[FR Doc No: 2011-26161]
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE
Antitrust Division
United States v. Morgan Stanley; Proposed Final Judgment and
Competitive Impact Statement
Notice is hereby given pursuant to the Antitrust Procedures and
Penalties Act, 15 U.S.C. 16(b)-(h), that a proposed Final Judgment,
Stipulation and Competitive Impact Statement have been filed with the
United States District Court for the Southern District of New York in
United States of America v. Morgan Stanley, Civil Action No. 11-Civ-
6875. On September 30, 2011, the United States filed a
[[Page 62844]]
Complaint alleging that a subsidiary of Morgan Stanley entered into an
agreement with KeySpan Corporation, the likely effect of which was to
increase prices in the New York City (NYISO Zone J) Capacity Market, in
violation of Section 1 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. 1. The proposed
Final Judgment, submitted at the same time as the Complaint, requires
Morgan Stanley to pay the government $4.8 million dollars.
Copies of the Complaint, proposed Final Judgment and Competitive
Impact Statement are available for inspection at the Department of
Justice, Antitrust Division, Antitrust Documents Group, 450 Fifth
Street NW., DC 20530 Suite 1010 (telephone: 202-514-2481), on the
Department of Justice's Web site at https://www.justice.gov/atr, and at
the Office of the Clerk of the United States District Court for the
Southern District of New York. Copies of these materials may be
obtained from the Antitrust Division upon request and payment of the
copying fee set by Department of Justice regulations.
Public comment is invited within 60 days of the date of this
notice. Such comments, and responses thereto, will be published in the
Federal Register and filed with the Court. Comments should be directed
to William H. Stallings, Chief, Transportation Energy and Agriculture
Section, Antitrust Division, Department of Justice, Washington, DC
20530, (telephone: 202-514-9323).
Patricia A. Brink,
Director of Civil Enforcement.
United States District Court for the Southern District of New York
United States of America, U.S. Department of Justice, Antitrust
Division, 450 5th Street, NW., Suite 8000, Washington, DC 20530,
Plaintiff,
v.
Morgan Stanley, 1585 Broadway, New York, N.Y. 10036, Defendant.
Civil Action No.: 11-civ-6875.
Complaint
The United States of America, acting under the direction of the
Attorney General of the United States, brings this civil antitrust
action under Section 4 of the Sherman Act, as amended, 15 U.S.C. 4, to
obtain equitable and other relief from Defendant's violation of Section
1 of the Sherman Act, as amended, 15 U.S.C. 1.
On January 18, 2006, KeySpan Corporation (``KeySpan'') and Morgan
Stanley Capital Group Inc. (``MSGC''), a subsidiary of defendant Morgan
Stanley,\1\ executed an agreement (the ``Morgan/KeySpan Swap'') that
ensured that KeySpan would withhold substantial output from the New
York City electricity generating capacity market, a market that was
created to ensure the supply of sufficient generation capacity for New
York City consumers of electricity. The likely effect of the Morgan/
KeySpan Swap was to increase capacity prices for the retail electricity
suppliers who must purchase capacity, and, in turn, to increase the
prices consumers pay for electricity. For its part, Morgan enjoyed
profits arising from revenues earned in connection with the Morgan/
KeySpan Swap.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1\ MSCG and Morgan Stanley are collectively referred to
hereinafter as ``Morgan.''
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
I. Introduction
1. Between 2003 and 2006, KeySpan, the largest seller of
electricity generating capacity (``installed capacity'') in the New
York City market, earned substantial revenues due to tight supply
conditions. Because purchasers of capacity required almost all of
KeySpan's output to meet expected demand, KeySpan's ability to set
price levels was limited only by a regulatory ceiling (called a ``bid
cap''). Indeed, the market price for capacity was consistently at or
near KeySpan's bid cap, with KeySpan sacrificing sales on only a small
fraction of its capacity.
2. But market conditions were about to change. Two large, new
electricity generation plants were slated to come on line in 2006 (with
no exit expected until at least 2009), breaking the capacity shortage
that had kept prices at the capped levels.
3. KeySpan could prevent the new capacity from lowering prices by
withholding a substantial amount of its own capacity from the market.
This ``bid the cap'' strategy would keep market prices high, but at a
significant cost--the sacrificed sales would reduce KeySpan's revenues
by as much as $90 million per year. Alternatively, KeySpan could
compete with its rivals for sales by bidding more capacity at lower
prices. This ``competitive strategy'' could earn KeySpan more than
bidding its cap, but it carried a risk--KeySpan's competitors could
undercut its price and take sales away, making the strategy less
profitable than ``bidding the cap.''
4. KeySpan searched for a way to avoid both the revenue decline
from bidding its cap and the revenue risks of competitive bidding. It
decided to enter into an agreement that gave it a financial interest in
the capacity of Astoria--KeySpan's largest competitor. By providing
KeySpan revenues on a larger base of sales, such an agreement would
make KeySpan's ``bid the cap'' strategy more profitable than a
successful competitive bid strategy. Rather than directly approach its
competitor, KeySpan turned to Morgan to act as the counterparty to the
agreement--the Morgan/KeySpan Swap--recognizing that Morgan would, and
in fact did, enter into an offsetting agreement with Astoria (the
``Morgan/Astoria Hedge'').
5. Morgan recognized that it could profit from combining the
economic interests of KeySpan and Astoria. Morgan extracted revenues by
entering into the financial instruments and thereby stepping into the
middle of the two companies. With KeySpan deriving revenues from both
its own and Astoria's capacity, the Morgan/KeySpan Swap removed any
incentive for KeySpan to bid competitively, locking it into bidding its
cap. Capacity prices remained as high as if no entry had occurred.
II. Defendant
6. Morgan Stanley is a Delaware corporation with its principal
place of business in New York City. Morgan Stanley provides diversified
financial services, operating a global asset management business,
investment banking services, and a global securities business,
including a commodities trading division. Morgan Stanley Capital Group,
Inc., a wholly owned subsidiary of Morgan Stanley, functions as and is
publicly referred to as the commodities trading division for the parent
company Morgan Stanley. In 2010, Morgan Stanley had revenues of $31.6
billion.
III. Jurisdiction and Venue
7. The United States files this complaint under Section 4 of the
Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. 4, seeking equitable relief from Defendant's
violation of Section 1 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. 1.
8. This court has jurisdiction over this matter pursuant to 15
U.S.C. 4 and 28 U.S.C. 1331 and 1337.
9. Defendant waives any objection to venue and personal
jurisdiction in this judicial district for the purpose of this
Complaint.
10. Defendant engaged in interstate commerce during the relevant
period of the allegations in this Complaint; Morgan is a worldwide
company that regularly engages in financial transactions across the
country and throughout the world.
IV. The New York City Installed Capacity Market
11. Sellers of retail electricity must purchase a product from
generators
[[Page 62845]]
known as ``installed capacity.'' Installed capacity is a product
created by the New York Independent System Operator (``NYISO'') to
ensure that sufficient generation capacity exists to meet expected
electricity needs. Companies selling electricity to consumers in New
York City are required to make installed capacity payments that relate
to their expected peak demand plus a share of reserve capacity (to
cover extra facilities needed in case a generating facility breaks
down). These payments assure that retail electric companies do not sell
more electricity than the system can deliver and also encourage
electric generating companies to build new facilities as needed.
12. The price for installed capacity has been set through auctions
administered by the NYISO. The rules under which these auctions are
conducted have changed from time to time. Unless otherwise noted, the
description of the installed capacity market in the following
paragraphs relates to the period May 2003 through March 2008.
13. Because transmission constraints limit the amount of energy
that can be imported into the New York City area from the power grid,
the NYISO requires retail providers of electricity to customers in New
York City to purchase 80% of their capacity from generators in that
region. The NYISO operates separate capacity auctions for the New York
City region (also known as ``In-City'' and ``Zone J''). The NYISO
organizes the auctions to serve two distinct seasonal periods, summer
(May through October) and winter (November through April). For each
season, the NYISO conducts seasonal, monthly and spot auctions in which
capacity can be acquired for all or some of the seasonal period.
14. In each of the types of auctions, capacity suppliers offer
price and quantity bids. Supplier bids are ``stacked'' from lowest-
priced to highest, and compared to the total amount of demand being
satisfied in the auction. The offering price of the last bid in the
``stack'' needed to meet requisite demand establishes the market price
for all capacity bid into that auction. Capacity bid at higher than
this price is unsold, as is any excess capacity bid at what becomes the
market price.
15. The New York City Installed Capacity (``NYC Capacity'') Market
constitutes a relevant geographic and product market.
16. The NYC Capacity Market is highly concentrated, with three
firms--KeySpan, NRG Energy, Inc. (``NRG'') and Astoria Generating
Company Acquisitions, L.L.C. (a joint venture of Madison Dearborn
Partners, LLC and US Power Generating Company, which purchased the
Astoria generating assets from Reliant Energy, Inc. in February 2006)--
controlling a substantial portion of generating capacity in the market.
Because purchasers of capacity require at least some of each of these
three suppliers' output to meet expected demand, the firms are subject
to a bid and price cap for nearly all of their generating capacity in
New York City and are not allowed to sell that capacity outside of the
NYISO auction process. The NYISO-set bid cap for KeySpan is the highest
of the three firms, followed by NRG and Astoria.
17. KeySpan possessed market power in the NYC Capacity Market.
18. It is difficult and time-consuming to build or expand
generating facilities within the NYC Capacity Market given limited
undeveloped space for building or expanding generating facilities and
extensive regulatory obligations.
V. Keyspan's Plan To Avoid Competition
19. From June 2003 through December 2005, KeySpan set the market
price in the New York City spot auction by bidding its capacity at its
cap. Given extremely tight supply and demand conditions, KeySpan needed
to withhold only a small amount of capacity to ensure that the market
cleared at its cap.
20. KeySpan anticipated that the tight supply and demand conditions
in the NYC Capacity Market would change in 2006, due to the entry of
approximately 1000 MW of new generation. Because of the addition of
this new capacity, KeySpan would have to withhold significantly more
capacity from the market and would earn substantially lower revenues if
it continued to bid all of its capacity at its bid cap. KeySpan
anticipated that demand growth and retirement of old generation units
would restore tight supply and demand conditions in 2009.
21. KeySpan could no longer be confident that ``bidding the cap''
would remain its best strategy during the 2006-2009 period. It
considered various competitive bidding strategies under which KeySpan
would compete with its rivals for sales by bidding more capacity at
lower prices. These strategies could potentially produce much higher
returns for KeySpan but carried the risk that competitors would
undercut its price and take sales away, making the strategy less
profitable than ``bidding the cap.''
22. KeySpan also considered acquiring Astoria's generating assets,
which were for sale. This would have solved the problem that new entry
posed for KeySpan's revenue stream, as Astoria's capacity would have
provided KeySpan with sufficient additional revenues to make continuing
to ``bid the cap'' its best strategy. KeySpan consulted with Morgan
about acquiring the assets. But KeySpan soon concluded that its
acquisition of its largest competitor would raise serious market power
issues and communicated that conclusion to Morgan.
23. Instead of purchasing the Astoria assets, KeySpan decided to
acquire a financial interest in substantially all of Astoria's
capacity. KeySpan would pay Astoria's owner a fixed revenue stream in
return for the revenues generated from Astoria's capacity sales in the
auctions.
24. KeySpan did not approach Astoria directly, instead approaching
Morgan to arrange a financial agreement providing KeySpan with payments
derived from the market clearing price for an amount of capacity
essentially equivalent to what Astoria owned. KeySpan recognized that
Morgan would need simultaneously to enter into an off-setting financial
agreement with another capacity supplier. Morgan agreed to such a Swap
but, as expected, informed KeySpan that the agreement was contingent on
Morgan entering into an offsetting agreement with the owner of the
Astoria assets.
VI. Morgan's Agreements With Keyspan and Astoria
25. Over the course of late 2005, Morgan negotiated the terms of
the derivative agreements with Astoria and KeySpan. Those negotiations
illustrate that Morgan recognized its role as a principal in
effectively combining the capacity of the two companies. Under the
terms initially discussed with Astoria, Morgan would have controlled
the bidding of Astoria's capacity. Morgan also proposed that the
financial derivative with Astoria be converted into a physical
contract, transferring the rights to Astoria's capacity to Morgan in
exchange for fixed payments, in the event that the structure of the
auction market was disrupted; and, at the same time, Morgan proposed in
its negotiations with KeySpan to transfer this physical capacity to
KeySpan should a market disruption occur.
26. On or about January 9, 2006, KeySpan and Morgan finalized the
terms of the Morgan/KeySpan Swap. Under the agreement, if the market
price for capacity was above $7.57 per kW-month, Morgan would pay
KeySpan the difference between the market price and $7.57 times 1800
MW; if the market price was below $7.57, KeySpan would
[[Page 62846]]
pay Morgan the difference times 1800 MW.
27. The Morgan/KeySpan Swap was executed on January 18, 2006. The
term of the Morgan/KeySpan Swap ran from May 2006 through April 2009.
28. On or about January 9, 2006, Morgan and Astoria finalized the
terms of the Morgan/Astoria Hedge. Under that agreement, if the market
price for capacity was above $7.07 per kW-month, Astoria would pay
Morgan the difference times 1800 MW; if the market price was below
$7.07, Astoria would be paid the difference times 1800 MW.
29. The Morgan/Astoria Hedge was executed on January 11, 2006. The
term of the Morgan/Astoria Hedge ran from May 2006 through April 2009,
matching the duration of the Morgan/KeySpan Swap.
VII. The Competitive Effect of the Morgan/Keyspan Swap
30. The clear tendency of the Morgan/KeySpan Swap was to alter
KeySpan's bidding in the NYC Capacity Market auctions.
31. Without the Morgan/KeySpan Swap, KeySpan likely would have
chosen from a range of potentially profitable competitive strategies in
response to the entry of new capacity. Had it done so, the price of
capacity would have declined. By transferring a financial interest in
Astoria's capacity to KeySpan, however, the Morgan/KeySpan Swap
effectively eliminated KeySpan's incentive to compete for sales in the
same way a purchase of Astoria or a direct agreement between KeySpan
and Astoria would have done. By providing KeySpan revenues from
Astoria's capacity, in addition to KeySpan's own revenues, the Morgan/
KeySpan Swap made bidding the cap KeySpan's most profitable strategy
regardless of its rivals' bids.
32. After the Morgan/KeySpan Swap went into effect in May 2006,
KeySpan paid and received revenues under the agreement with Morgan and
consistently bid its capacity at its cap even though a significant
portion of its capacity went unsold. Despite the addition of
significant new generating capacity in New York City, the market price
of capacity did not decline.
33. In August 2007, the State of New York conditioned the sale of
KeySpan to a new owner on the divestiture of KeySpan's Ravenswood
generating assets and required KeySpan to bid its New York City
capacity at zero from March 2008 until the divestiture was completed.
Since March 2008, the market price for capacity has declined.
34. But for the Morgan/KeySpan Swap, installed capacity likely
would have been procured at a lower price in New York City from May
2006 through February 2008.
35. From May 2006 to April 2008, Morgan earned approximately $21.6
million in net revenues from the Morgan/KeySpan Swap and the Morgan/
Astoria Hedge.
36. The Morgan/KeySpan Swap produced no countervailing
efficiencies.
VIII. Violation Alleged
37. Plaintiff incorporates the allegations of paragraphs 1 through
36 above.
38. Morgan entered into an agreement the likely effect of which has
been to increase prices in the NYC Capacity Market, in violation of
Section 1 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. 1.
IX. Prayer for Relief
Wherefore, Plaintiff prays:
39. That the Court adjudge and decree that the Morgan/KeySpan Swap
constitutes an illegal restraint in the sale of installed capacity in
the New York City market in violation of Section 1 of the Sherman Act;
40. That Plaintiff shall have such other relief, including
equitable monetary relief, as the nature of this case may require and
as is just and proper to prevent the recurrence of the alleged
violation and to dissipate the anticompetitive effects of the
violation; and
41. That Plaintiff recover the costs of this action.
Dated: September 30, 2011.
Respectfully submitted,
For Plaintiff United States.
Sharis A. Pozen,
Acting Assistant Attorney General for Antitrust.
Joseph F. Wayland,
Deputy Assistant Attorney General.
Patricia A. Brink,
Director of Civil Enforcement.
Wlliam H. Stallings,
Chief, Transportation, Energy & Agriculture Section.
Jade Eaton,
Attorney, Transportation, Energy & Agriculture Section, Antitrust
Division, U.S. Department of Justice, 450 Fifth Street, NW., Suite
8000, Washington, DC 20530, Telephone: (202) 353-1560, Facsimile:
(202) 616-2441, e-mail: jade.eaton@usdoj.gov.
J. Richard Doidge,
John W. Elias, Attorneys for the United States.
United States of America, Plaintiff,
v.
Morgan Stanley, Defendant.
Civil Action No.: 11-civ-6875.
Competitive Impact Statement
Plaintiff United States of America (``United States''), pursuant to
Section 2(b) of the Antitrust Procedures and Penalties Act (``APPA'' or
``Tunney Act''), 15 U.S.C. 16(b)-(h), files this Competitive Impact
Statement relating to the proposed Final Judgment submitted for entry
in this civil antitrust proceeding.
I. Nature and Purpose of the Proceedings
The United States brought this lawsuit against Defendant Morgan
Stanley (``Morgan'') on September 30, 2011, to remedy a violation of
Section 1 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. 1. In January 2006, Morgan
Stanley Capital Group Inc. (``MSGC''), a subsidiary of defendant Morgan
Stanley,\2\executed agreements with KeySpan Corporation (``KeySpan'')
and Astoria Generating Company Acquisitions, L.L.C. (``Astoria'') that
would effectively combine the economic interests of the two largest
competitors in the New York City electric capacity market. By creating
this combination, the likely effect of the agreements was to increase
capacity prices for the retail electricity suppliers who must purchase
capacity, and, in turn, to increase the prices consumers pay for
electricity.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\2\ MSCG and Morgan Stanley are collectively referred to
hereinafter as ``Morgan.''
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The proposed Final Judgment remedies this violation by requiring
Morgan to disgorge profits obtained through the anticompetitive
agreement. Under the terms of the proposed Final Judgment, Morgan will
surrender $4.8 million to the Treasury of the United States.
Disgorgement will deter Morgan and others from future violations of the
antitrust laws.
The United States and Morgan have stipulated that the proposed
Final Judgment may be entered after compliance with the APPA, unless
the United States withdraws its consent. Entry of the proposed Final
Judgment would terminate this action, except that this Court would
retain jurisdiction to construe, modify, and enforce the proposed Final
Judgment and to punish violations thereof.
II. Description of the Events Giving Rise to the Alleged Violation of
the Antitrust Laws
A. The Defendant
Morgan Stanley is a Delaware corporation with its principal place
of business in New York City. Morgan Stanley provides diversified
financial services, operating a global asset
[[Page 62847]]
management business, investment banking services, and a global
securities business, including a commodities trading division. In 2010,
Morgan Stanley had revenues of $31.6 billion. Morgan Stanley Capital
Group, Inc., a wholly owned subsidiary of Morgan Stanley, functions as
and is publicly referred to as the commodities trading division for the
parent company Morgan Stanley.
B. The Market
In the state of New York, sellers of retail electricity must
purchase a product from generators known as installed capacity
(``capacity'').\3\ Electricity retailers are required to purchase
capacity in an amount equal to their expected peak energy demand plus a
share of reserve capacity. These payments assure that retail electric
companies do not use more electricity than the system can deliver and
encourage electric generating companies to build new facilities as
needed. Because transmission constraints limit the amount of energy
that can be imported into the New York City area from the power grid,
the New York Independent System Operator (``NYISO'') requires retail
providers of electricity to customers in New York City to purchase 80%
of their capacity from generators in that region. Thus, the New York
City Installed Capacity (``NYC Capacity'') Market constitutes a
relevant geographic and product market.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\3\ Except where noted otherwise, this description pertains to
the market conditions that existed from May 2003 through March 2008.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The price for installed capacity has been set through auctions
administered by the NYISO. The NYISO organizes the auctions to serve
two distinct seasonal periods, summer (May though October) and winter
(November through April). For each season, the NYISO conducts seasonal,
monthly, and spot auctions in which capacity can be acquired for all or
some of the seasonal period. Capacity suppliers offer price and
quantity bids in each of these three auctions. Supplier bids are
``stacked'' from lowest-priced to highest. The stack is then compared
to the amount of demand. The offering price of the last bid in the
``stack'' needed to meet requisite demand establishes the market price
for all capacity sold into that auction. Any capacity bid at higher
than this price is unsold, as is any excess capacity bid at what
becomes the market price.
The NYC Capacity Market was highly concentrated during the relevant
period, with three firms--Astoria, NRG Energy, Inc., and KeySpan--
controlling a substantial portion of the market's generating capacity.
These three were designated as pivotal suppliers by the Federal Energy
Regulatory Commission, meaning that at least some of each of these
three suppliers' output was required to satisfy demand. The three firms
were subject to bid and price caps--KeySpan's being the highest--for
nearly all of their generating capacity in New York City and were not
allowed to sell their capacity outside of the NYISO auction process.
C. The Alleged Violation
1. KeySpan Assesses Plans for Changed Market Conditions
From June 2003 through December 2005, almost all installed capacity
in the market was needed to meet demand. With these tight market
conditions, KeySpan could sell almost all of its capacity into the
market, even while bidding at its cap. KeySpan did so, and the market
cleared at the price established by the cap, with only a small fraction
of KeySpan's capacity remaining unsold.
KeySpan anticipated that the tight supply and demand conditions in
the NYC Capacity Market would end in 2006 due to the entry into the
market of approximately 1000 MW of generation capacity, and would not
return until 2009 with the retirement of old generation units and
demand growth.
KeySpan could no longer be confident that ``bid the cap'' would
remain its best strategy during the 2006-2009 period. The ``bid the
cap'' strategy would keep market prices high, but at a significant
cost. KeySpan would have to withhold a significant additional amount of
capacity to account for the new entry. The additional withholding would
reduce KeySpan's revenues by as much as $90 million per year.
Alternatively, KeySpan could compete with its rivals for sales by
bidding more capacity at lower prices. KeySpan considered various
competitive bidding strategies. These could potentially produce much
higher returns for KeySpan than bidding the cap but carried the risk
that competitors would undercut its price and take sales away, making
the strategy potentially less profitable than bidding the cap.
KeySpan also considered acquiring Astoria's generating assets from
Reliant Energy, Inc., which was putting them up for sale. This would
have solved the problem that new entry posed for KeySpan's revenue
stream, as Astoria's capacity would have provided KeySpan with
sufficient additional revenues to make continuing to ``bid the cap''
its best strategy. Simultaneously, Morgan was interested in buying the
same assets and seeking a strategic partner with whom to bid. Morgan
and KeySpan discussed such a partnership and the market power issues of
a bid involving KeySpan. KeySpan soon concluded that its acquisition of
its largest competitor would raise serious market power issues and
communicated that conclusion to Morgan.
2. Morgan Facilitates the Anticompetitive and Unlawful Agreement
Instead of purchasing the Astoria assets, KeySpan decided to
acquire a financial interest in substantially all of Astoria's
capacity. KeySpan would pay Astoria's owner a fixed revenue stream in
return for the revenues generated from Astoria's capacity sales in the
auctions.
KeySpan realized that it could not approach the owner of Astoria
assets directly, so it turned to Morgan to act as a counter-party.
Morgan agreed to serve as the counter-party but informed KeySpan that
the agreement was contingent on it entering into an offsetting
agreement with the owner of the Astoria generating assets.
On or about January 9, 2006, KeySpan and Morgan finalized the terms
of a financial derivative arrangement between the two companies, ``the
Morgan/KeySpan Swap.'' Under the agreement, if the market price for
capacity was above $7.57 per kW-month, Morgan would pay KeySpan the
difference between the market price and $7.57 times 1800 MW; if the
market price was below $7.57, KeySpan would pay Morgan the difference
times 1800 MW. The Morgan/KeySpan Swap was executed on January 18,
2006. The term of the Morgan/KeySpan Swap ran from May 2006 through
April 2009.
On or about January 9, 2006, Morgan and Astoria finalized the terms
of the offsetting agreement (``Morgan/Astoria Hedge''). Under that
agreement, if the market price for capacity was above $7.07 per kW-
month, Astoria would pay Morgan the difference times 1800 MW; if the
market price was below $7.07, Astoria would be paid the difference
times 1800 MW. The Morgan/Astoria Hedge was executed on January 11,
2006. The term of the Morgan/Astoria Hedge ran from May 2006 through
April 2009, matching the duration of the Morgan/KeySpan Swap.
Morgan earned approximately $21.6 million in net revenues from the
Morgan/KeySpan Swap and the Morgan/Astoria Hedge.
3. The Effect of the Morgan/KeySpan Swap
After the Morgan/KeySpan Swap went into effect in May 2006, KeySpan
[[Page 62848]]
consistently bid its capacity into the capacity auctions at its cap
even though a significant portion of its capacity went unsold. Despite
the addition of significant new generating capacity in New York City,
the market price of capacity did not decline.
The clear tendency of the Morgan/KeySpan Swap was to alter
KeySpan's bidding in the NYC Capacity Market auctions. The swap
effectively eliminated KeySpan's incentive to compete for sales in the
same way a purchase of Astoria or a direct agreement between KeySpan
and Astoria would have done. By adding revenues from Astoria's capacity
to KeySpan's own, the Morgan/KeySpan Swap made bidding the cap
KeySpan's most profitable strategy regardless of its rivals' bids.
Without the swap, KeySpan likely would have chosen from a range of
potentially profitable competitive strategies in response to the entry
of new capacity and, had it done so, the price of capacity would have
declined. The swap produced no countervailing efficiencies.
III. United States v. Keyspan Corporation
On February 22, 2010, the United States filed suit against KeySpan
for its role in the Morgan/KeySpan Swap. Simultaneous with the filing
of its Complaint, the United States filed a proposed Final Judgment
requiring KeySpan to pay to the United States $12 million as
disgorgement of ill-gotten gains. See Complaint, United States v.
KeySpan Corp., No. 10-1415 (S.D.N.Y. Feb. 22, 2010). After completion
of the procedures set forth in the Tunney Act, including public notice
and comment, the United States moved for entry of the proposed Final
Judgment. In the course of making its public interest determination,
the Court found that disgorgement is available to remedy violations of
the Sherman Act. See United States v. KeySpan Corp., 763 F. Supp. 2d
633, 638-641. The KeySpan Final Judgment was entered on February 2,
2011.
IV. Explanation of the Proposed Final Judgment
The proposed Final Judgment requires Morgan to disgorge profits
gained as a result of its unlawful agreement restraining trade. Morgan
is to surrender $4.8 million to the Treasury of the United States.
KeySpan, pursuant to a Final Judgment sought by the United States,
has surrendered $12 million as a result of its role in the Morgan/
KeySpan Swap.\4\ See United States v. KeySpan Corp., 763 F. Supp. 2d
633, 637-38 (S.D.N.Y. 2011). Securing similar disgorgement from the
other responsible party to the anticompetitive agreement will protect
the public interest by depriving Morgan of a substantial portion of the
fruits of the agreement. The effect of the swap agreement was to
effectively combine the economic interests of KeySpan and Astoria,
thereby permitting KeySpan to increase prices above competitive rates,
and this result could not have been achieved without Morgan's
participation in the swap agreement. Requiring disgorgement in these
circumstances will thus protect the public interest by deterring Morgan
and other parties from entering into similar financial agreements that
result in anticompetitive effects in the underlying markets, or from
otherwise engaging in similar anticompetitive conduct in the future.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\4\ Had the KeySpan case proceeded to trial, the United States
would have sought disgorgement of the approximately $49 million in
net revenues that KeySpan received under the Swap, contending that
these net revenues reflected the value that KeySpan received from
trading the uncertainty of competing for the certainty of the bid-
the-cap strategy. See Plaintiff United States's Response to Public
Comments at 14-18, United States v. KeySpan Corp., No. 10-1415
(S.D.N.Y. June 11, 2010).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The $4.8 million disgorgement amount is the product of settlement
and accounts for litigation risks and costs. While the disgorged sum
represents less than all of Morgan's net transaction revenues under the
two agreements,\5\ disgorgement will effectively fulfill the remedial
goals of the Sherman Act to ``prevent and restrain'' antitrust
violations as it will send a message of deterrence to those in the
financial services community considering the use of derivatives for
anticompetitive ends.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\5\ Had the case against Morgan proceeded to trial, the United
States would have sought disgorgement of the $21.6 million in net
transaction revenues Morgan earned under both the Morgan/KeySpan
Swap and the Morgan/Astoria Hedge. At trial, Morgan--in addition to
raising arguments as to its lack of liability in general--would have
disputed that the entire $21.6 million earned under both agreements
would be cognizable as ill-gotten gains.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
V. Remedies Available to Potential Private Litigants
Section 4 of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. 15, provides that any
person who has been injured as a result of conduct prohibited by the
antitrust laws may bring suit in federal court to recover three times
the damages the person has suffered, as well as costs and reasonable
attorneys' fees. Entry of the proposed Final Judgment will neither
impair nor assist the bringing of any private antitrust damage action.
Under the provisions of Section 5(a) of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C.
16(a), the proposed Final Judgment has no prima facie effect in any
subsequent private lawsuit that may be brought against Morgan.
VI. Procedures Available for Modification of the Proposed Final
Judgment
The United States and the Defendant have stipulated that the
proposed Final Judgment may be entered by the Court after compliance
with the provisions of the APPA, provided that the United States has
not withdrawn its consent. The APPA conditions entry upon the Court's
determination that the proposed Final Judgment is in the public
interest.
The APPA provides a period of at least sixty (60) days preceding
the effective date of the proposed Final Judgment within which any
person may submit to the United States written comments regarding the
proposed Final Judgment. Any person who wishes to comment should do so
within sixty (60) days of the date of publication of this Competitive
Impact Statement in the Federal Register, or the last date of
publication in a newspaper of the summary of this Competitive Impact
Statement, whichever is later. All comments received during this period
will be considered by the United States, which remains free to withdraw
its consent to the proposed Final Judgment at any time prior to the
Court's entry of judgment. The comments and the response of the United
States will be filed with the Court and published in the Federal
Register.
Written comments should be submitted to: William H. Stallings,
Chief, Transportation, Energy & Agriculture Section, Antitrust
Division, United States Department of Justice, 450 Fifth Street, NW.;
Suite 8000, Washington, DC 20530.
The proposed Final Judgment provides that the Court retains
jurisdiction over this action, and the parties may apply to the Court
for any order necessary or appropriate for the modification,
interpretation, or enforcement of the Final Judgment.
VII. Alternatives to the Proposed Final Judgment
The United States considered, as an alternative to the proposed
Final Judgment, a full trial on the merits against the Defendant. The
United States is satisfied, however, that the disgorgement of profits
is an appropriate remedy in this matter. A disgorgement remedy should
deter Morgan and others from engaging in similar conduct and thus
achieves a significant portion of the relief the United States would
have
[[Page 62849]]
obtained through litigation but avoids the time, expense, and
uncertainty of discovery and a full trial on the merits of the
Complaint.
VIII. Standard of Review Under the APPA for Proposed Final Judgment
The Clayton Act, as amended by the APPA, requires that proposed
consent judgments in antitrust cases brought by the United States be
subject to a sixty-day comment period, after which the court shall
determine whether entry of the proposed Final Judgment ``is in the
public interest.'' 15 U.S.C. 16(e)(1). In making that determination,
the court is directed to consider:
(A) The competitive impact of such judgment, including termination
of alleged violations, provisions for enforcement and modification,
duration of relief sought, anticipated effects of alternative remedies
actually considered, whether its terms are ambiguous, and any other
competitive considerations bearing upon the adequacy of such judgment
that the court deems necessary to a determination of whether the
consent judgment is in the public interest; and
(B) the impact of entry of such judgment upon competition in the
relevant market or markets, upon the public generally and individuals
alleging specific injury from the violations set forth in the complaint
including consideration of the public benefit, if any, to be derived
from a determination of the issues at trial.
15 U.S.C. 16(e)(1)(A) & (B); see generally United States v. KeySpan
Corp., 763 F. Supp. 2d 633, 637-38 (S.D.N.Y. 2011) (WHP) (discussing
Tunney Act standards); United States v. SBC Commc'ns, Inc., 489 F.
Supp. 2d 1 (D.D.C. 2007) (assessing standards for public interest
determination). In considering these statutory factors, the court's
inquiry is necessarily a limited one as the United States is entitled
to ``broad discretion to settle with the Defendant within the reaches
of the public interest.'' United States v. Microsoft Corp., 56 F.3d
1448, 1461 (D.C. Cir. 1995).
Under the APPA a court considers, among other things, the
relationship between the remedy secured and the specific allegations
set forth in the United States' complaint, whether the decree is
sufficiently clear, whether enforcement mechanisms are sufficient, and
whether the decree may positively harm third parties. See Microsoft, 56
F.3d at 1458-62. With respect to the adequacy of the relief secured by
the decree, the court's function is ``not to determine whether the
proposed [d]ecree results in the balance of rights and liabilities that
is the one that will best serve society, but only to ensure that the
resulting settlement is within the reaches of the public interest.''
KeySpan, 763 F. Supp. 2d at 637 (quoting United States v. Alex Brown &
Sons, Inc., 963 F. Supp. 235, 238 (S.D.N.Y. 1997) (internal quotations
omitted). In making this determination, ``[t]he [c]ourt is not
permitted to reject the proposed remedies merely because the court
believes other remedies are preferable. [Rather], the relevant inquiry
is whether there is a factual foundation for the government's decision
such that its conclusions regarding the proposed settlement are
reasonable.'' Id. at 637-38 (quoting United States v. Abitibi-
Consolidated Inc., 584 F. Supp. 2d 162, 165 (D.D.C. 2008).\6\ The
government's predictions about the efficacy of its remedies are
entitled to deference.\7\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\6\ United States v. Bechtel Corp., 648 F.2d 660, 666 (9th Cir.
1981) (``The balancing of competing social and political interests
affected by a proposed antitrust consent decree must be left, in the
first instance, to the discretion of the Attorney General.''). See
generally Microsoft, 56 F.3d at 1461 (discussing whether ``the
remedies [obtained in the decree are] so inconsonant with the
allegations charged as to fall outside of the `reaches of the public
interest' '').
\7\ Microsoft, 56 F.3d at 1461 (noting the need for courts to be
``deferential to the government's predictions as to the effect of
the proposed remedies''); United States v. Archer-Daniels-Midland
Co., 272 F. Supp. 2d 1, 6 (D.D.C. 2003) (noting that the court
should grant due respect to the United States' prediction as to the
effect of proposed remedies, its perception of the market structure,
and its views of the nature of the case).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Courts have greater flexibility in approving proposed consent
decrees than in crafting their own decrees following a finding of
liability in a litigated matter. ``[A] proposed decree must be approved
even if it falls short of the remedy the court would impose on its own,
as long as it falls within the range of acceptability or is `within the
reaches of public interest.' '' United States v. Am. Tel. & Tel. Co.,
552 F. Supp. 131, 151 (D.D.C. 1982) (citations omitted) (quoting United
States v. Gillette Co., 406 F. Supp. 713, 716 (D. Mass. 1975)), aff'd
sub nom. Maryland v. United States, 460 U.S. 1001 (1983); see also
United States v. Alcan Aluminum Ltd., 605 F. Supp. 619, 622 (W.D. Ky.
1985) (approving the consent decree even though the court would have
imposed a greater remedy). To meet this standard, the United States
``need only provide a factual basis for concluding that the settlements
are reasonably adequate remedies for the alleged harms.'' SBC Commc'ns,
489 F. Supp. 2d at 17.
Moreover, the court's role under the APPA is limited to reviewing
the remedy in relationship to the violations that the United States has
alleged in its Complaint, and does not authorize the court to
``construct [its] own hypothetical case and then evaluate the decree
against that case.'' Microsoft, 56 F.3d at 1459; KeySpan, 763 F. Supp.
2d at 638 (``A court must limit its review to the issues in the
complaint * * *.''). Because the ``court's authority to review the
decree depends entirely on the government's exercising its
prosecutorial discretion by bringing a case in the first place,'' it
follows that ``the court is only authorized to review the decree
itself,'' and not to ``effectively redraft the complaint'' to inquire
into other matters that the United States did not pursue. Microsoft, 56
F.3d at 1459-60.
In its 2004 amendments, Congress made clear its intent to preserve
the practical benefits of utilizing consent decrees in antitrust
enforcement, adding the unambiguous instruction that ``[n]othing in
this section shall be construed to require the court to conduct an
evidentiary hearing or to require the court to permit anyone to
intervene.'' 15 U.S.C. 16(e)(2). This language effectuates what
Congress intended when it enacted the Tunney Act in 1974, as Senator
Tunney explained: ``[t]he court is nowhere compelled to go to trial or
to engage in extended proceedings which might have the effect of
vitiating the benefits of prompt and less costly settlement through the
consent decree process.'' 119 Cong. Rec. 24,598 (1973) (statement of
Senator Tunney). Rather, the procedure for the public interest
determination is left to the discretion of the court, with the
recognition that the court's ``scope of review remains sharply
proscribed by precedent and the nature of Tunney Act proceedings.'' SBC
Commc'ns, 489 F. Supp. 2d at 11.\8\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\8\ See United States v. Enova Corp., 107 F. Supp. 2d 10, 17
(D.D.C. 2000) (noting that the ``Tunney Act expressly allows the
court to make its public interest determination on the basis of the
competitive impact statement and response to comments alone'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
IX. Determinative Documents
There are no determinative materials or documents within the
meaning of the APPA that the United States considered in formulating
the proposed Final Judgment.
Dated: September 30, 2011.
Respectfully submitted,
For Plaintiff
the United States of America.
Jade Alice Eaton,
Trial Attorney, United States Department of Justice, Antitrust
Division, Transportation, Energy & Agriculture Section, 450 5th
Street, NW., Suite 8000, Washington, DC 20530,
[[Page 62850]]
Telephone: (202) 307-6316, jade.eaton@usdoj.gov.
United States of America, Plaintiff,
v.
Morgan Stanley, Defendant.
Civil Action No.
Final Judgment
Whereas Plaintiff United States of America filed its Complaint
alleging that Defendant Morgan Stanley (``Morgan'') violated Section 1
of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. 1, and Plaintiff and Morgan, through
their respective attorneys, having consented to the entry of this Final
Judgment without trial or adjudication of any issue of fact or law, for
settlement purposes only, and without this Final Judgment constituting
any evidence against or an admission by Morgan for any purpose with
respect to any claim or allegation contained in the Complaint:
Now, Therefore, before the taking of any testimony and without
trial or adjudication of any issue of fact or law herein, and upon the
consent of the parties hereto, it is hereby Ordered, Adjudged, and
Decreed:
I. Jurisdiction
This Court has jurisdiction of the subject matter herein and of
each of the parties consenting hereto. The Complaint states a claim
upon which relief may be granted to the United States against Morgan
under Sections 1 and 4 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. 1 and 4.
II. Applicability
This Final Judgment applies to Morgan and each of its successors,
assigns, and to all other persons in active concert or participation
with it who shall have received actual notice of the Settlement
Agreement and Order by personal service or otherwise.
III. Relief
A. Within thirty (30) days of the entry of this Final Judgment,
Morgan shall pay to the United States the sum of four million eight
hundred thousand dollars ($4,800,000.00).
B. The payment specified above shall be made by wire transfer.
Before making the transfer, Morgan shall contact Janie Ingalls, of the
Antitrust Division's Antitrust Documents Group, at (202) 514-2481 for
wire transfer instructions.
C. In the event of a default in payment, interest at the rate of
eighteen (18) percent per annum shall accrue thereon from the date of
default to the date of payment.
IV. Retention of Jurisdiction
This Court retains jurisdiction to enable any party to this Final
Judgment to apply to this Court at any time for further orders and
directions as may be necessary or appropriate to carry out or construe
this Final Judgment, to modify any of its provisions, to enforce
compliance, and to punish violations of its provisions. Upon
notification by the United States to the Court of Morgan's payment of
the funds required by Section III above, this Section IV will have no
further force or effect.
V. Public Interest Determination
Entry of this Final Judgment is in the public interest. The parties
have complied with the requirements of the Antitrust Procedures and
Penalties Act, 15 U.S.C. 16, including making copies available to the
public of this Final Judgment, the Competitive Impact Statement, and
any comments thereon and Plaintiff's responses to comments. Based upon
the record before the Court, which includes the Competitive Impact
Statement and any comments and response to comments filed with the
Court, entry of this Final Judgment is in the public interest.
Dated:-----------------------------------------------------------------
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
United States District Judge.
[FR Doc. 2011-26161 Filed 10-7-11; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 4410-11-P