Universal Service-Intercarrier Compensation Transformation, 49401-49408 [2011-20322]
Download as PDF
srobinson on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with PROPOSALS
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 154 / Wednesday, August 10, 2011 / Proposed Rules
specific industries for industry-focused
compensation reviews. What specific
categories of data would be most useful
for identifying contractors in specific
industries for industry focused
compensation reviews?
7. OFCCP is exploring the possibility
of using the data collected through the
tool to identify opportunities for
nationwide multi-establishment
compensation reviews.
(a) What specific categories of data
would be most useful for conducting
compensation analyses across a
contractor’s various establishments?
(b) What are the benefits and
drawbacks of collecting contractor’s
compensation data on a nationwide
basis rather than on an individual
establishment basis?
(c) What are the benefits and
drawbacks of collecting contractor’s
compensation data on a nationwide
basis in addition to an individual
establishment basis?
8. The data collection tool may
require contractors to submit data on an
establishment basis. Given the possible
designs of the tool and its proposed
uses, OFCCP is interested in learning of
any practical concerns contractors may
have regarding responding to the
compensation data request and how
contractors currently record and
maintain compensation data.
Specifically:
(a) What general tasks would be
required by a contractor in order to
provide the compensation data?
(b) What categories of compensationrelated data are currently maintained in
computer-based personnel or payroll
systems?
(c) What specific costs and/or benefits
would be associated with collecting this
type of data?
9. OFCCP is considering designing the
tool so that it may be used by
contractors to conduct self-assessments
of their compensation decisions. What
specific categories of data would be
most useful to contractors interested in
using the tool in this manner?
10. What were the strengths and
weaknesses of the compensation section
of the 2000 EO Survey? 17
11. OFCCP is considering requiring
contractors to submit data
electronically. What factors should
OFCCP take into consideration when
designing this data collection tool?
Interested parties should suggest
preferred formats—i.e., a web-based
form (like the EEO–1), excel
17 A blank copy of the 2000 EO Survey will be
posted in www.regulations.gov as a supporting
document to this ANPRM. To view the EO Survey
in https://www.regulations.gov search by RIN
number 1250–AA03.
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:42 Aug 09, 2011
Jkt 223001
spreadsheet, etc. What types of
databases are currently used, if any, to
maintain personnel and payroll data?
12. An option that OFCCP is
considering is the possibility of
requiring businesses that are bidding on
future Federal contracts to submit
compensation data as part of the
Request for Proposal process. In such a
case, the data collected may be used for
trend analyses as well as targeting
contractors for post-award compliance
reviews. What are the benefits and
drawbacks of administering the data
collection tool in this manner?
13. Should OFCCP decide to expand
the scope of the compensation data
collection tool beyond supply and
service contractors to include
construction contractors, what factors or
issues particularly relevant to such
contractors should OFCCP keep in mind
when designing and implementing the
tool?
14. Are there other constructive
suggestions for the design, content,
analysis, and implementation of a
compensation data collection tool?
15. Consistent with the Regulatory
Flexibility Act, OFCCP must consider
the impact of any proposed rule on
small entities, including small
businesses, small nonprofit
organizations and small governmental
jurisdictions with populations under
50,000. In response to this ANPRM,
OFCCP encourages small entities to
provide data on how they may be
impacted by the requirement to provide
the compensation data requested by the
new data collection tool.
(a) The Department seeks public
comment on the types of small entities
and any estimates of the numbers of
small entities that may be impacted by
this rule.
(b) The Department seeks public
comment on the potential identifiable
costs of the data collection on small
entities.
(c) The Department seeks public
comment on any possible alternatives to
the proposed measures that would allow
OFCCP to achieve its objectives while
minimizing any likely adverse impact to
small businesses such as allowing
smaller establishments to submit
administrative data—for example,
quarterly unemployment insurance tax
payments that would include wage
information—augmented by gender and
race/ethnicity identification, but
without other compensation details.
OFCCP encourages interested parties
to comment on these questions and the
related questions of how OFCCP can
maximize the potential value of this
data collection tool while taking into
account the reporting burden created for
PO 00000
Frm 00021
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
49401
contractors and the technology and/or
analytic burdens placed on the agency.
Dated: August 5, 2011
Patricia A. Shiu,
Director, Office of Federal Contract
Compliance Programs.
[FR Doc. 2011–20299 Filed 8–9–11; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 4510–45–P
FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS
COMMISSION
47 CFR Parts 36, 54, 61, 64, and 69
[WC Docket No. 10–90; DA 11–1348]
Universal Service—Intercarrier
Compensation Transformation
AGENCY: Federal Communications
Commission.
ACTION: Proposed rule.
SUMMARY: In this document, the Federal
Communications Commission
(Commission) seeks targeted comment
on certain issues in the Universal
Service—Intercarrier Compensation
Transformation proceeding. The
Commission has received several
proposals in the record in this
proceeding to which we would like to
receive comment from interested
parties. This opportunity for additional,
targeted comment will facilitate
comprehensive universal service and
intercarrier compensation reform.
DATES: Comments on the Pubic Notice
are due on or before August 24, 2011,
and reply comments are due on or
before August 31, 2011.
ADDRESSES: You may submit comments,
identified by WC Docket Nos. 10–90,
07–135, 05–337, 03–109; GN Docket No.
09–51; CC Docket Nos. 01–92, 96–45, by
any of the following methods:
• Federal eRulemaking Portal: https://
www.regulations.gov. Follow the
instructions for submitting comments.
• Federal Communications
Commission’s Web Site: https://
fjallfoss.fcc.gov/ecfs2/. Follow the
instructions for submitting comments.
• People with Disabilities: Contact the
FCC to request reasonable
accommodations (accessible format
documents, sign language interpreters,
CART, etc.) by e-mail: FCC504@fcc.gov
or phone: (202) 418–0530 or TTY: (202)
418–0432.
For detailed instructions for
submitting comments and additional
information on the notice process, see
the SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION section
of this document.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
Katie King, Telecommunications Access
Policy Division, Wireline Competition
E:\FR\FM\10AUP1.SGM
10AUP1
srobinson on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with PROPOSALS
49402
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 154 / Wednesday, August 10, 2011 / Proposed Rules
Bureau, (202) 418–7400, Daniel Ball,
Pricing Policy Division, Wireline
Competition Bureau, (202) 418–1520 or
Sue McNeil, Auctions and Spectrum
Access Division, Wireless
Telecommunications Bureau at (202)
418–0660, or TTY: (202) 418–0484.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: This is a
synopsis of the Public Notice in WC
Docket No. 10–90, GN Docket No. 09–
51, WC Docket No. 07–135, WC Docket
No. 05–337, CC Docket No. 01–92, CC
Docket No. 96–45, and WC Docket No.
03–109, DA 11–1348 released August 3,
2011. The complete text of this
document is available for inspection
and copying during normal business
hours in the FCC Reference Information
Center, Portals II, 445 12th Street, SW.,
Room CY–A257, Washington, DC 20554.
The document may also be purchased
from the Commission’s duplicating
contractor, Best Copy and Printing, Inc.,
445 12th Street, SW., Room CY–B402,
Washington, DC 20554, telephone (800)
378–3160 or (202) 863–2893, facsimile
(202) 863–2898, or via the Internet at
https://www.bcpiweb.com. It is also
available on the Commission’s Web site
at https://www.fcc.gov.
Pursuant to §§ 1.415 and 1.419 of the
Commission’s rules, interested parties
may file comments and reply comments
on or before the dates indicated on the
first page of this document. Comments
may be filed using: (1) The
Commission’s Electronic Comment
Filing System (ECFS); (2) the Federal
Government’s eRulemaking Portal; or (3)
by filing paper copies. See Electronic
Filing of Documents in Rulemaking
Proceedings, 63 FR 24121, May 1, 1998.
• Electronic Filers: Comments may be
filed electronically using the Internet
by accessing the ECFS: https://
www.fcc.gov/cgb/ecfs/ or the Federal
eRulemaking Portal: https://
www.regulations.gov. Filers should
follow the instructions provided on
the website for submitting comments.
Æ For ECFS filers, if multiple docket
or rulemaking numbers appear in the
caption of this proceeding, filers must
transmit one electronic copy of the
comments for each docket or
rulemaking number referenced in the
caption. In completing the transmittal
screen, filers should include their full
name, U.S. Postal Service mailing
address, and the applicable docket or
rulemaking number. Parties may also
submit an electronic comment by
Internet e-mail. To get filing
instructions, filers should send an email to ecfs@fcc.gov, and include the
following words in the body of the
message, ‘‘get form.’’ A sample form and
directions will be sent in response.
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:42 Aug 09, 2011
Jkt 223001
Æ Paper Filers: Parties who choose to
file by paper must file an original and
four copies of each filing. If more than
one docket or rulemaking number
appears in the caption of this
proceeding, filers must submit two
additional copies for each additional
docket or rulemaking number.
• Filings can be sent by hand or
messenger delivery, by commercial
overnight courier, or by first-class or
overnight U.S. Postal Service mail
(although we continue to experience
delays in receiving U.S. Postal Service
mail). All filings must be addressed to
the Commission’s Secretary, Office of
the Secretary, Federal Communications
Commission.
Æ All hand-delivered or messengerdelivered paper filings for the
Commission’s Secretary must be
delivered to FCC Headquarters at 445
12th St., SW., Room TW–A325,
Washington, DC 20554. The filing hours
at this location are 8 a.m. to 7 p.m. All
hand deliveries must be held together
with rubber bands or fasteners. Any
envelopes must be disposed of before
entering the building.
Æ Commercial overnight mail (other
than U.S. Postal Service Express Mail
and Priority Mail) must be sent to 9300
East Hampton Drive, Capitol Heights,
MD 20743.
Æ U.S. Postal Service first-class,
Express, and Priority mail should be
addressed to 445 12th Street, SW.,
Washington, DC 20554.
In addition, one copy of each pleading
must be sent to the Commission’s
duplicating contractor, Best Copy and
Printing, Inc, 445 12th Street, SW.,
Room CY–B402, Washington, DC 20554;
Web site: https://www.bcpiweb.com;
phone: 1–800–378–3160. Furthermore,
one copy of each pleading must be sent
to Charles Tyler, Telecommunications
Access Policy Division, Wireline
Competition Bureau, 445 12th Street,
SW., Room 5–A452, Washington, DC
20554; e-mail: Charles.Tyler@fcc.gov.
Filings and comments are also
available for public inspection and
copying during regular business hours
at the FCC Reference Information
Center, Portals II, 445 12th Street, SW.,
Room CY–A257, Washington, DC 20554.
Copies may also be purchased from the
Commission’s duplicating contractor,
BCPI, 445 12th Street, SW., Room CY–
B402, Washington, DC 20554.
Customers may contact BCPI through its
Web site: https://www.bcpiweb.com, by
e-mail at fcc@bcpiweb.com, by
telephone at (202) 488–5300 or (800)
378–3160 (voice), (202) 488–5562 (tty),
or by facsimile at (202) 488–5563.
To request materials in accessible
formats for people with disabilities
PO 00000
Frm 00022
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
(Braille, large print, electronic files,
audio format), send an e-mail to
fcc504@fcc.gov or call the Consumer &
Governmental Affairs Bureau at (202)
418–0530 (voice) or (202) 418–0432
(TTY). Contact the FCC to request
reasonable accommodations for filing
comments (accessible format
documents, sign language interpreters,
CART, etc.) by e-mail: FCC504@fcc.gov;
phone: (202) 418–0530 or TTY: (202)
418–0432.
This matter shall be treated as a
‘‘permit-but-disclose’’ proceeding in
accordance with the Commission’s ex
parte rules. Persons making oral ex
parte presentations are reminded that
memoranda summarizing the
presentations must contain summaries
of the substance of the presentation and
not merely a listing of the subjects
discussed. More than a one or two
sentence description of the views and
arguments presented generally is
required. Other rules pertaining to oral
and written ex parte presentations in
permit-but-disclose proceedings are set
forth in section 1.1206(b) of the
Commission’s rules.
Discussion
In order to comprehensively reform
and modernize the universal service
fund (USF) and intercarrier
compensation (ICC) system in light of
recent technological, market, and
regulatory changes, on February 9, 2011,
the Commission released the Universal
Service and Intercarrier Compensation
Transformation Notice of Proposed
Rulemaking (USF–ICC Transformation
NPRM). The NPRM sought public
comment on reforms to modernize USF
and ICC for broadband, control the size
of the USF as it transitions to support
broadband, require accountability from
companies receiving support, and use
market-driven and incentive-based
policies that maximize the value of
scarce program resources for the benefit
of consumers. Previously, on October
14, 2010, the Commission released the
Universal Service Reform—Mobility
Fund Notice of Proposed Rulemaking
(Mobility Fund NPRM), 75 FR 67060,
which proposed to expand mobile voice
and data service availability by using a
market-based mechanism to award onetime support from accumulated USF
reserves. In response to the USF–ICC
Transformation NPRM, a number of
parties have offered specific proposals
for reform, including a proposal by the
State Members of the Federal-State
Universal Service Joint Board (State
Members), the ‘‘RLEC Plan’’ put forward
by the Joint Rural Associations, and the
‘‘America’s Broadband Connectivity
Plan’’ filed by six Price Cap Companies
E:\FR\FM\10AUP1.SGM
10AUP1
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 154 / Wednesday, August 10, 2011 / Proposed Rules
(‘‘ABC Plan’’). We seek comment on
how these proposals comport with the
Commission’s articulated objectives and
statutory requirements. We invite
comment on specific aspects of the
proposals and on additional issues that
are not fully developed in the record.
I. Universal Service
A. Separate Support for Mobile
Broadband
• Several parties propose that the
Commission create two separate
components of the Connect America
Fund, one focused on ensuring that
consumers receive fixed voice and
broadband service (which could be
wired or wireless) from a single
provider of last resort in areas that are
uneconomic to serve with fixed service,
and one focused on providing ongoing
support for mobile voice and broadband
service in areas that are uneconomic to
serve with mobile service (i.e., a Mobile
Connect America Fund), with the two
components together providing annual
support under a defined budget. We
seek comment on providing separate
funding for fixed broadband (wired or
wireless) and mobility. How should the
Commission set the relative budgets of
two separate components? How should
the budgets be revised over time?
• In the USF/ICC Transformation
NPRM, the Commission sought
comment on phasing down high-cost
support for competitive eligible
telecommunications carriers
(competitive ETCs) over 5 years and
transitioning such support to the CAF.
To what extent would projected savings
associated with intercarrier
compensation reform for wireless
carriers as proposed in the ABC Plan
help offset reductions in high-cost
support for competitive ETCs? We ask
parties to substantiate their comments
with data and remind parties that they
may file data under the protective order
issued in this proceeding.
srobinson on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with PROPOSALS
B. Elimination of Rural and Non-Rural
Carrier Distinctions
• In the USF/ICC Transformation
NPRM, the Commission sought
comment on two potential paths for the
long term CAF: (1) Use a competitive,
technology-neutral bidding process to
determine CAF recipients; or (2) offer
the current voice carrier of last resort a
right of first refusal to serve the area for
an amount of ongoing support
determined by a cost model, with a
competitive process if the incumbent
refuses the offer. Several parties that
jointly filed a letter proposing a path for
reform propose a hybrid system in
which support would be determined
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:42 Aug 09, 2011
Jkt 223001
under a combination of a forwardlooking cost model and competitive
bidding in areas served by price cap
companies, while companies that today
are regulated under a rate of return
methodology would continue to receive
support based on embedded costs, albeit
with greater accountability and cost
controls. Similarly, the State Members
suggest that a forward-looking model be
used for price cap companies, while rate
of return companies would have the
option of receiving support under a
model or based on embedded costs. We
seek comment on the policy
implications of eliminating the current
references to rural and non-rural carriers
in our rules and of adopting two
separate approaches to determining
support for carriers that operate in rural
areas that are uneconomic to serve,
based on whether a company is
regulated under rate of return or price
caps in the interstate jurisdiction.
C. CAF Support for Price Cap Areas
1. Use of a Model.
Æ Both the State Members and the
ABC Plan would use a forward-looking
model to determine support amounts for
areas where there is no private sector
business case to offer broadband. We
seek comment on what information
would need to be filed in the record
regarding the CostQuest Broadband
Analysis Tool (CQBAT model) for the
Commission to consider adopting it, as
proposed in the ABC Plan.
Æ The ABC Plan proposes using one
technology to determine the modeled
costs of 4 Mbps download/768 kbps
upload service, while permitting
support recipients to use any technology
capable of meeting those requirements.
Should the amounts determined by a
model be adjusted to reflect the
technology actually deployed? Is ten
years an appropriate time frame for
determining support levels, given
statutory requirements for an evolving
definition of universal service? Should
the model reflect the costs of building
a network capable of meeting future
consumer demand for higher bandwidth
that reasonably can be anticipated five
years from now?
2. Right of First Refusal (ROFR).
Æ The ABC Plan would give an
incumbent local exchange carrier (LEC)
the opportunity to accept or decline a
model-determined support amount in a
wire center if the incumbent LEC has
already made high-speed Internet
service available to more than 35
percent of the service locations in the
wire center. We seek comment on this
proposal. Would aggregating census
blocks to something other than a wire
center be an improvement to the
PO 00000
Frm 00023
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
49403
proposal? Is 35 percent a reasonable
threshold? Should areas that are
overlapped by an unsubsidized
facilities-based provider be excluded
when calculating the percentage? Is the
opportunity to exercise a ROFR
reasonable consideration for an
incumbent LEC’s ongoing responsibility
to serve as a voice carrier of last resort
throughout its study areas, even as
legacy support flows are being phased
down? Should any ROFR go to the
provider with the most broadband
deployment in the relevant area rather
than automatically to the incumbent
LEC? Alternatively, if there are at least
two providers in the relevant area that
exceed the threshold, should the
Commission use competitive bidding to
select the support recipient?
3. Public Interest Obligations.
Æ Last year, the Federal-State Joint
Board on Universal Service
recommended that the Commission
adopt a principle ‘‘that universal service
support should be directed where
possible to networks that provide
advanced services, as well as voice
services.’’ If that recommendation is
adopted, how could the CQBAT model
be improved to account for the costs of
providing both broadband and voice
service?
Æ The State Members propose that
recipients of support meet specific
broadband build-out milestones at years
1, 3 and 5 of deployment. A company
that exceeded a specified minimum
standard, but failed to meet the higher
standard at a given milestone would
receive a pro rata share of support. We
seek comment on what specific interim
milestones would be effective in
ensuring that carriers receiving CAF
support are building out broadband at a
reasonable rate during the specified
build-out period.
Æ The ABC Plan proposes that CAF
recipients provide broadband service
that meets specified bandwidth
requirements to all locations within a
supported area, but does not address the
pricing of such services or usage
allowances. Should the Commission
adopt reporting requirements for
supported providers regarding pricing
and usage allowances to facilitate its
ability to ensure that consumers in rural
areas are receiving reasonably
comparable services at reasonably
comparable rates?
4. Eligible Telecommunications
Carrier (ETC) Requirements.
Æ The ABC Plan proposes a
procurement model, in which recipients
of CAF support incur service obligations
only to the extent they agree to perform
them in explicit agreements with the
Commission, and CAF recipients are
E:\FR\FM\10AUP1.SGM
10AUP1
49404
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 154 / Wednesday, August 10, 2011 / Proposed Rules
srobinson on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with PROPOSALS
free to use any technology, wireline or
wireless, that meets specified
bandwidth and service requirements.
What specific rule changes to the
Commission’s rules, including part 54,
subpart C of the Commission’s rules,
would be necessary to implement such
a proposal?
5. State Role.
Æ The State Members and other
commenters propose an ongoing role for
states in monitoring and oversight over
recipients of universal service support.
We seek comment on specific
illustrative areas where the states could
work in partnership with the
Commission in advancing universal
service, subject to a uniform national
framework, and invite comments on
other suggestions. For example:
• Were the Commission to adopt a
ROFR mechanism, could the states
determine whether a provider has
already made a substantial broadband
investment in a particular area, and
therefore would be eligible to be offered
support amounts determined under a
forward-looking model?
• Should ETCs be required to file
copies of all information submitted to
the Commission regarding compliance
with public interest obligations with the
states, as well as with USAC?
• The ABC Plan contemplates that
CAF recipients would serve all business
and residential locations within a
supported area, but does not specifically
address the obligation to serve newly
built locations within a supported area
over the ten-year term of the funding.
Should states be charged with
determining whether any charges for
extending service to newly constructed
buildings are reasonable, based on local
conditions?
• Should states collect information
regarding customer complaints,
including complaints about unfulfilled
service requests and inadequate service?
D. Reforms for Rate-of-Return Carriers
• In light of the RLEC Plan and the
Joint Letter, as well as proposals by the
State Members, we seek comment below
on specific issues relating to universal
service support for rate-of-return
companies.
Æ Re-examining the Interstate Rate of
Return. The Joint Letter proposes that
CAF calculations for areas served by
rate-of-return companies would be
calculated using a 10 percent interstate
rate of return. The State Members
recommended that the rate of return for
universal service calculations be set at
8.5 percent. We seek comment on what
data the Commission would need to
have in the record to enable it to waive
the requirements in part 65 of the
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:42 Aug 09, 2011
Jkt 223001
Commission’s rules for a rate of return
prescription proceeding, so that the
Commission could quickly adopt a
particular rate of return.
Æ Corporate Operations Expense
Limitation Formula. We seek comment
on applying the following formula to
limit recovery of corporate operations
expenses for high-cost loop support
(HCLS), interstate common line support
(ICLS), and local switching support
(LSS).
For study areas with 6,000 or fewer
working loops, the monthly amount per
loop shall be limited to;
$42.337¥(.00328 × the number of
working loops) or $50,000/the
number of working loops,
whichever is greater
For study areas with more than 6,000
working loops, but fewer than 17,888
working loops, the monthly amount per
loop shall be limited to:
$3.007 + (117,990/number of working
loops)
For study areas with 17,888 or more
working loops, the monthly amount per
loop shall be limited to:
$9.52 per working loop.
Æ Eliminating Support for Areas with
an Unsubsidized Competitor. In
responding to the NPRM, the RLEC Plan
suggested that the Commission could
establish a process to reduce an
incumbent’s support if another
facilities-based provider proves that it
provides sufficient broadband and voice
service to at least 95 percent of the
households in the incumbent’s study
area without any support or crosssubsidy. We seek comment on such a
process, including how to allocate costs
to the remaining portions of the
incumbent’s study area for purposes of
determining universal service support.
Would a cost model be a way to allocate
costs between the subsidized and
unsubsidized portion of a rate-of-return
study area that overlaps substantially
with an unsubsidized competitor?
Could state commissions administer
proceedings to consider such
challenges, similar to the suggestion in
the ABC Plan that state commissions
could elect to determine which census
blocks served by price cap companies
have unsubsidized competitors, and
therefore are not eligible for CAF
support?
Æ Limits on Reimbursable Operating
and Capital Costs. We seek comment on
limiting reimbursable levels of capital
investment and operating expenses for
LSS.
E. Ensuring Consumer Equity
• Rate Benchmark. In the USF/ICC
Transformation NPRM, the Commission
PO 00000
Frm 00024
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
sought comment on the use of a rate
benchmark to encourage states to
rebalance their rates and ensure that
universal service does not subsidize
carriers with artificially low rates. In
response to the NPRM, one commenter
suggested that we should develop a
benchmark for voice service and reduce
a carrier’s high-cost support by the
amount that its rate falls below the
benchmark. Under such an approach,
the Commission would reduce intrastate
universal service support (specifically,
HCLS for rural carriers and high-cost
model support (HCMS) for non-rural
carriers) dollar for dollar during the
transition to CAF to the extent the
company’s local rates do not meet the
specified benchmark. These reductions
would not flow to other recipients. We
seek comment on this proposal and
proposed variations on it. Should we set
the initial benchmark using the most
recently available data that the
Commission has regarding local rates?
For example, according to the 2008
Reference Book of Rates, the average
monthly charge for flat-rate service was
$15.62 per month. Using the same data,
the average monthly charge for flat-rate
service, plus subscriber line charges of
$5.74 per month, would total $21.36 per
month. Should the benchmark rise over
a period of three years, for instance,
with an end point of $25–$30 (or some
other amount) for the total of the local
residential rate, federal subscriber line
charge (SLC), state subscriber line
charge, mandatory extended area service
charges, and per-line contribution to a
state’s high cost fund, if one exists?
Should this benchmark be the same as
the ICC benchmark?
• Total company earnings review.
The State Members recommended that a
Provider of Last Resort Fund include a
total company earnings review to limit
a supported carrier from earning more
than a reasonable return. We seek to
further develop the record on the
mechanics of conducting an earnings
review to ensure that universal service
is not providing excessive support to the
detriment of consumers across the
United States.
Æ We seek comment on the State
Members’ recommendation that, at least
initially, the support mechanism should
not factor in either the revenues or
marginal costs of video operations to
avoid the risk of subsidizing video
operating losses attributable to
unregulated programming costs.
Æ We seek comment on what total
company rate of return should be used,
what the mechanism should be for
reducing support to the extent that total
company rate of return is exceeded, and
E:\FR\FM\10AUP1.SGM
10AUP1
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 154 / Wednesday, August 10, 2011 / Proposed Rules
how often a total company earnings
review should be conducted.
Æ We seek comment on what carriers
should be required to submit to USAC,
in a standard format, to facilitate a total
company earnings review. For example,
should we require submission of the
audited financial statements for the
incumbent LEC, a consolidated balance
sheet and income statement for the
incumbent LEC and its affiliates, a list
of affiliates, a schedule showing
dividends paid to shareholders or
patronage refunds distributed to
members of cooperatives for the last five
years, a Cost Allocation Manual, an
explanation of how revenues from
bundled services are booked, a trial
balance of accounts at a Class B
accounting level or greater, and the
number of retail customers served by
the incumbent LEC and its affiliates for
voice and broadband service?
srobinson on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with PROPOSALS
F. Highest-Cost Areas
• The ABC Plan would rely on
satellite broadband to serve extremely
high-cost areas. We seek comment on a
proposal by ViaSat to create a
Competitive Technologies Fund to
distribute support through a
combination of a reverse auction and
consumer vouchers to enable consumers
in highest-cost areas to obtain service
from wireless, satellite, or other
providers.
• We also seek comment on what
obligations are appropriate to impose on
recipients of funding, as a condition of
receiving support, to facilitate
provisioning by others in areas the
recipients are not obligated to serve. For
example, Public Knowledge has
proposed to require recipients to make
interconnection points and backhaul
capacity available so that unserved
high-cost communities could deploy
their own broadband networks. Should
recipients’ Acceptable Use Policies also
be required to allow customers to share
their broadband connections with
unserved customers nearby, for
example, through the use of WiFi
combined with directional antenna
technology?
G. CAF Support for Alaska, Hawaii,
Tribal Lands, U.S. Territories, and Other
Areas
• GCI has proposed an Alaskaspecific set of universal service reforms
that it asserts better reflect the operating
conditions in Alaska and the lower level
of broadband and mobile deployment in
that state. We seek comment on this
proposal for Alaska, and ask whether
this, or a similar approach, would also
be warranted for Hawaii, Tribal lands,
the U.S. Territories, or other particular
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:42 Aug 09, 2011
Jkt 223001
areas, and how we should consider such
proposals in light of the Tribal lands
exclusion from the current cap on highcost support for competitive ETCs. We
further seek comment on other
proposals relating to Alaska and Hawaii
that have been proposed in the record.
We further seek comment on how such
proposals could be improved, if the
Commission were to adopt a plan to
constrain the size of the CAF and access
restructuring within a $4.5 billion
annual budget, and whether, in the
alternative, other modifications are
warranted to the national policy to
better reflect operating conditions in
these areas.
H. Implementing Reform Within a
Defined Budget
• The ABC Plan recommends a fiveyear transition for phasing down legacy
funding, concomitant with a phase-in of
potential CAF support, including
potential access recovery associated
with intercarrier compensation reform;
the Joint Letter suggests several
potential measures that could be taken
to keep support totals within a budget,
such as phasing in funding for mobility,
deferring CAF funding for study areas
served by particular price cap
companies, or deferring reductions in
intercarrier compensation. We seek
comment on the implications of these
and alternative proposals, including
variations to the Commission’s prior
proposals regarding safety net additive
(SNA) and LSS, for ensuring that total
funding remains within a defined
budget.
I. Interim Reforms for Price Cap Carriers
• As an interim step, Windstream,
Frontier and CenturyLink suggest that
the Commission could immediately
target support that currently flows to
price cap carriers to the highest-cost
wire centers within their service
territories, using a regression analysis
based on the Commission’s existing
high-cost model to estimate wire center
forward-looking costs for both rural and
non-rural price cap carriers. We seek
comment on this proposal and how it
relates to other proposals in the record
for comprehensive reform.
Æ In addition to combining and
distributing HCLS and HCMS, should
the Commission also include funds
currently provided through LSS and
SNA to price cap carriers? Should we
also include funds currently provided to
price cap carriers through interstate
access support (IAS) and frozen ICLS?
Æ Should the Commission increase
annual HCMS support by an additional
amount, such as $100 to $200 million,
to be repurposed from ongoing
PO 00000
Frm 00025
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
49405
reductions in support for companies
that have chosen to relinquish universal
service funding? Should we impose a
cap on the amount of support a carrier
is eligible to receive for a wire center?
For instance, should that cap be set at
$250 per line per month, similar to the
Commission’s proposal for a cap in total
support for all existing recipients?
Æ What public interest obligations for
using funding for broadband-capable
networks should apply to carriers
receiving support under this approach?
Should carriers receiving such support
be prohibited from using the funds in
areas that are served by an unsubsidized
facilities-based broadband provider?
Æ Do any special circumstances exist
in the states of Alaska and Hawaii, or
Territories and Tribal lands generally, or
other areas, that warrant a different
approach for price cap carriers serving
such areas, if the Commission were to
adopt this interim measure?
II. Intercarrier Compensation
A. Federal-State Roles
1. Federal Framework.
• The ABC Plan proposes that the
Commission set the framework to
reduce intrastate access rates, and
recovery to the extent necessary for
those reduced intrastate access revenues
would come from the federal
jurisdiction through a combination of
federal SLC increases and federal
universal service support.
Æ How would this aspect of the ABC
Plan affect states in different stages of
intrastate access reform—those that
have undertaken significant reform and
moved intrastate rates to parity with
interstate rates, those in the process of
reform, and states that have not yet
initiated reform?
Æ The ABC Plan provides a uniform,
consistent framework for reform across
all states. We seek comment on whether
the ABC Plan could be improved by
providing states incentives to increase
artificially low consumer rates or create
state USFs for example through the use
of a consumer monthly rate ceiling or
benchmark or by requiring states to
contribute a certain amount per line of
recovery to offset intrastate rate
reductions?
• In calculating access recovery, the
ABC Plan proposes a $30 ‘‘rate
benchmark’’ for price cap carriers, and
the Rate-of-Return plan proposes a $25
benchmark, both of which are
structured as a ceiling on consumer rate
increases (via a federal SLC), to limit
increases on consumer rates in states
where such rates have already been
raised as part of intrastate access reform.
Is this ceiling sufficient to mitigate any
E:\FR\FM\10AUP1.SGM
10AUP1
srobinson on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with PROPOSALS
49406
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 154 / Wednesday, August 10, 2011 / Proposed Rules
potential impact on consumers in states
that have already begun reforms (and
thus are already paying increased local
rates and/or state universal service
contributions associated with such
reform) relative to consumers in states
that have not yet undertaken such
reforms (for which all recovery would
come through the federal mechanism in
the ABC Plan)? Should there be
different rate benchmarks for different
carriers or should there be a single
benchmark?
• In the ABC Plan, in calculating
access recovery, the initial consumer
monthly rate is taken as a snapshot in
time as of January 1, 2012. In lieu of a
snapshot, and in order to avoid
deterring states from rebalancing local
rates and/or establishing state USFs,
should the rate used to determine access
recovery be the ‘‘higher of’’ (1) The rate
as of January 2012 and (2) the rate at
future points before annual access
recovery amounts are calculated? In this
scenario, any increased consumer rates
as a result of state reforms, would count
toward the benchmark, more accurately
reflecting the actual consumer burden at
that time.
• A rate benchmark could also be
used as an imputation for a certain level
of end-user recovery for intrastate rate
reductions, rather than as a ceiling on
federal SLC increases. For instance, the
Ad Hoc Telecommunications Users
Committee proposes a local rate
benchmark that could be imputed,
rather than used as a ceiling, and
commenters propose a range of possible
benchmarks from $25–$30. Would an
imputation approach better encourage
states that currently depend on long
distance consumers to help subsidize
local phone service for their local
consumers to bring consumer rates to
levels more comparable to the national
average? What would be the appropriate
level for such a benchmark, and should
it be phased in over time?
• Instead of or in addition to a rate
benchmark, should states be responsible
for contributing a certain dollar amount
per line to aid in access recovery? The
State Members, for example, suggest
that states contribute $2 per line for
purposes of universal service. In this
scenario, a state would be responsible
for recovery of $2 per line of reduced
intrastate access revenues, which could
be imputed to carriers before they
become eligible for federal recovery.
Does this approach appropriately
balance the interests of consumers in
states that already have implemented
some reforms, with the associated
burden of reform being born by
consumers in those states, rather than
federal recovery mechanisms? If so,
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:42 Aug 09, 2011
Jkt 223001
should states that already have a state
universal service fund be exempted
completely from this per-line
contribution, or only to the extent of, for
example, the $2 per line state
contribution to recovery?
2. State-Federal Framework.
• In the alternative, the State
Members propose that the states reform
intrastate rates and that the Commission
facilitate this reform through state
inducements rather than a federal
framework. We seek comment on this
proposal.
Æ To address concerns that some
states may not reform intrastate access
charges, we seek comment on a
framework, similar to a proposal in the
USF/ICC Transformation NPRM, under
which states have three years to develop
an intrastate reform plan. Under this
alternative, after three years, the
Commission would set a transition for
reducing intrastate access rates and
deny any further federal recovery to
offset reduced intrastate revenue.
Æ If the Commission adopts the statefederal framework approach advocated
by the State Members, how can the
Commission best incent states to reform
intrastate access rates? Should the
Commission match some federal
universal service dollars to a state
universal service fund for states that are
using such a fund to reform intrastate
access charges? Such matching could be
structured in several different ways,
including on a per-line basis (such as
$1–2), as a percentage of the state
contribution, or on an aggregate state
basis. We seek further comment on how
such a match should be structured to
provide adequate inducements and
maintain our commitment to control the
size of the federal high cost fund.
• Under the framework of leaving
reform of intrastate rates initially to the
states, the Commission would begin
immediate reforms of interstate access
charges. We seek comment on a glide
path for the Commission to reduce all
interstate access rate elements. Should
the length of the rate transition vary,
providing three years for price cap
carriers and five years for rate-of-return
carriers, given that rate of return
carriers’ interstate access rates are
higher at the outset? What should the
transition be for competitive LECs?
Would an approach that provides
different transitions for different types
of carriers, whether competitive, price
cap or rate-of-return LEC raise any
policy concerns? We also seek comment
on whether the Commission should
reduce originating interstate access rates
and, if so, whether we should require
the reductions at the same time or only
PO 00000
Frm 00026
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
after terminating rates have been
reduced.
B. Scope of Reform
• We seek comment on the approach
outlined in the ABC Plan to reform
substantially terminating rates for end
office switching while taking a more
limited approach to reforming certain
transport elements and originating
access. Would any problematic
incentives, such as arbitrage schemes,
arise from or be left in place by such an
approach, and if so, what could be done
to mitigate them?
C. Recovery Mechanism
• We seek comment on the
appropriate recovery mechanism for ICC
reform, including the ABC Plan’s and
the Joint Letter’s recovery proposals. We
also seek comment on the relative
merits and incentives for carriers
associated with an alternative approach
that provides more predictable recovery
amounts, such as the alternative
described below.
1. Federal-State Role in Recovery.
Æ As noted above, the ABC Plan
proposes to shift recovery for reduced
intrastate access charge revenues to the
federal jurisdiction. Could the
Commission achieve more
comprehensive reform of intercarrier
compensation rate elements if recovery
is achieved through a federal-state
partnership? We seek comment above
on different means by which states
could share responsibility for recovery
of reduced intrastate access revenues.
2. Price Cap Carriers.
Æ For price cap carriers electing to
receive support from the transitional
access replacement mechanism, the
ABC Plan’s recovery proposal includes
annual true-ups to adjust for possible
increases or decreases in minutes of use.
Although minutes of use for incumbent
LECs have been declining, the ABC
Plan’s proposal establishing how VoIP
minutes are included in the intercarrier
compensation system prospectively and
addressing phantom traffic could cause
minutes of use to flatten or possibly
even increase. In addition, the ABC Plan
would treat all VoIP traffic as interstate,
which potentially could reduce the
minutes billed at intrastate access rates
(depending upon existing payment
practices). Thus the true-up approach
could result in the need for additional
recovery, including additional federal
universal service funding. We seek
comment on alternatives to the true-up
process.
Æ For example, as an alternative to
true ups, we seek comment on a
baseline for recovery that would be 2011
E:\FR\FM\10AUP1.SGM
10AUP1
srobinson on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with PROPOSALS
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 154 / Wednesday, August 10, 2011 / Proposed Rules
access revenues subject to reform,
reduced by 10% annually to account for
decline in demand (i.e., 90% of 2011
revenues in year one (2012), 81.0% in
year two (2013), 72.9% in year three
(2014), 65.6% in year four (2015), etc.).
This (or a similar framework that may
be suggested by commenters) would be
a brightline, predictable approach that
would not include true-ups, regardless
of whether demand declines more
quickly or more slowly. If carriers
reduce costs or are more efficient, this
approach would enable carriers to
realize the benefits of these savings.
3. Rate of Return Carriers.
Æ We seek comment below on an
alternative approach for recovery (or
other approaches that commenters
might suggest) that would maintain the
predictable revenue stream associated
with rate of return principles while also
providing carriers with better incentives
for efficient investment and operations.
This option would provide a fixed
percentage of recovery (which could be
100%) of all reduced terminating access
charges (both intrastate and interstate)
based on year 2011 revenues, but
without true-ups to reflect changes in
the revenue requirement historically
used for interstate access charges. This
recovery mechanism would lock in
revenue streams, including intrastate
access revenues, which have been
declining annually for many interstate
rate-of-return carriers. It thus provides
more predictable revenue recovery
while also providing incentives for
carriers to reduce costs and realize the
benefits of these cost savings. The
eligible recovery amount would be
recovered through end-user charges and
universal service support as described
in the Joint Letter’s proposal. We also
seek comment on the duration of
recovery funding under this alternative.
Should it be phased out over time
following the completion of rate
reforms, such as with the loss of
demand?
4. Reciprocal Compensation.
Æ The ABC Plan’s proposal provides
recovery for reductions in reciprocal
compensation rates to the extent they
are above $0.0007, but the ABC Plan
estimates on the impact of the federal
universal service fund do not include
estimated recovery from reciprocal
compensation. We ask whether
providing federal universal service
support for reductions in reciprocal
compensation rates strikes the
appropriate policy balance as we seek to
control the size of the universal service
fund, and whether there are alternatives
to such an approach.
5. Originating Access.
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:42 Aug 09, 2011
Jkt 223001
Æ If the Commission were to address
originating access as part of
comprehensive reform, should the
Commission treat originating access
revenues differently from terminating
access revenues for recovery purposes
since, in many cases, the originating
incumbent LEC’s affiliate is offering the
long distance service? For example, is it
necessary to provide any recovery for
the originating access that an incumbent
LEC historically charged for originating
calls from the retail long distance
customers of its affiliate?
Æ Alternatively, should recovery for
such originating access take the form of
a flat per-customer charge imposed on
the incumbent LEC’s long distance
affiliate for each of its presubscribed
customers? Should such a flat
originating access replacement charge
be used for recovery of all originating
access revenues more generally? How
would any of these approaches be
implemented? Should any flat
originating access replacement charge
differ by end-user customer class (such
as residential vs. business), by level of
demand, or otherwise?
Æ We seek the following data to help
us evaluate originating access reform:
• Separately for price cap and rate-ofreturn incumbent LECs, the number of
(1) Long distance minutes that the
average customer originates; (2) 8YY
minutes that the average customer
originates; and (3) long distance and
8YY minutes that the average customer
receives (terminating minutes); and
• Whether the ratio of originated long
distance minutes to originated 8YY
minutes varies materially with the level
of the customers’ expenditure on
telecommunications services.
D. Impact on Consumers
• We seek comment on how to ensure
that consumers realize benefits of
reduced long distance and wireless rates
as part of intercarrier compensation
reform. The ABC Plan attaches a paper
by Professor Jerry Hausman analyzing
the consumer benefits of intercarrier
compensation reform. Should the
potential realization of consumer pass
through benefits from intercarrier
compensation reform be left to the
market, as Professor Hausman asserts, or
should any steps be taken to ensure that
such benefits are realized by
consumers? If so, what steps should be
taken?
• The ABC Plan permits incumbent
carriers to increase the consumer SLC
up to $9.20 before increasing the
multiline business SLC, although
multiline business SLCs potentially
could increase once consumer SLCs
reach that level. To decrease the
PO 00000
Frm 00027
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
49407
potential burden on consumers and the
federal universal service fund, should
multiline business customers also see a
modest SLC increase and, if so, how
much?
• The ABC Plan permits incumbent
carriers to increase consumer SLC rates
$0.50–0.75 per year for five years or
until the consumer’s rate reaches the
rate benchmark of $30. Similarly, the
Joint Letter permits incumbent carriers
to increase consumer SLC rates $0.75
per year for six years or until the
consumer’s rate reaches the rate
benchmark of $25. Professor Hausman’s
paper indicates that companies are
constrained by competition, which
could mean that companies may not be
able to increase SLC rates on consumers.
We seek comment on the actual likely
consumer impact of SLC increases, in
the aggregate and with as much
granularity (e.g., by company, by type of
state, by specific state) as can be
provided. We also seek comment on
proposals that the need for any recovery
should be based on the carrier’s
showing of need based on its operations
more broadly.
• We seek the following data to help
us quantify consumer benefits from
intercarrier compensation reform:
Æ If ICC termination rates that
currently exceed $0.0007 are reduced to
$0.0007, the services where pass
through is likely to occur (perhaps, for
example, long distance, wireless service,
8YY services and monthly line rentals)
and the likely extent of that pass
through; and
Æ Estimates of demand elasticities for
those services where pass through is
likely to occur.
E. VoIP ICC
• Implementation. We seek comment
on the implementation of the ABC
Plan’s proposal for VoIP intercarrier
compensation. Under that proposal,
VoIP access traffic would be subject to
intercarrier compensation rates different
from rates applied to other access traffic
during the first part of the transition.
Æ How would VoIP traffic subject to
the ICC framework be identified for
purposes of the proposed tariffing
regime?
Æ Would it be feasible to use call
record information or factors or ratios to
identify the portion of overall traffic that
is (or reasonably is considered to be)
relevant VoIP traffic, perhaps subject to
certification or audits?
Æ Should the Commission identify a
‘‘safe harbor’’ percentage of VoIP traffic
for use in this context? If so, what
should be the factual basis for such a
safe harbor? For example, Global
Crossing estimates ‘‘that on average
E:\FR\FM\10AUP1.SGM
10AUP1
srobinson on DSK4SPTVN1PROD with PROPOSALS
49408
Federal Register / Vol. 76, No. 154 / Wednesday, August 10, 2011 / Proposed Rules
roughly fifty to sixty percent of the
traffic [on its network] is VoIP.’’ Would
that, or other data, provide a basis for
a safe harbor?
Æ Are there alternative mechanisms
besides tariffs that could be used to
determine the amount of VoIP traffic
exchanged between two carriers for
purposes of the VoIP ICC framework,
and if so, what would be the relative
merits of such an approach?
• Call Signaling. In the USF/ICC
Transformation NPRM the Commission
proposed to apply new call signaling
rules designed to address phantom
traffic to telecommunications carriers
and interconnected VoIP providers.
Some commenters have expressed
concerns about whether and how the
proposed rules would apply to one-way
interconnected VoIP providers. In
particular, we seek to further develop
the record regarding possible
implementation of any new call
signaling rules that apply to one-way
interconnected VoIP providers.
Æ If call signaling rules apply to oneway interconnected VoIP providers,
how could these requirements be
implemented? Would one-way
interconnected VoIP providers be
required to obtain and use numbering
resources? If not, how could the new
signaling rules operate for originating
callers that do not have a telephone
number?
Æ If one-way interconnected VoIP
providers were permitted to use a
number other than an actual North
American Numbering Plan (NANP)
telephone number associated with an
originating caller in required signaling,
would such use lead to unintended or
undesirable consequences? If so, should
other types of carriers or entities also be
entitled to use alternate numbering?
Æ Would there need to be numbering
resources specifically assigned in the
context of one-way VoIP services? Are
there other signaling issues that we
should consider with regard to one-way
VoIP calls?
Æ If call signaling rules were to apply
signaling obligations to one-way
interconnected VoIP providers, at what
point in a call path should the required
signaling originate, i.e., at the gateway
or elsewhere?
Æ To what extent are such
requirements necessary to implement
the ABC Plan’s and Joint Letter’s
proposals that billing for VoIP traffic be
based on call detail information? More
broadly, what particular call detail
information would be used for this
purpose? What are the relative
advantages or disadvantages of treating
such call detail information as
dispositive for determining whether
VerDate Mar<15>2010
17:42 Aug 09, 2011
Jkt 223001
access charges or reciprocal
compensation rates apply?
Federal Communications Commission.
Marcus Maher,
Deputy Chief, Pricing Policy Division,
Wireline Competition Bureau.
[FR Doc. 2011–20322 Filed 8–9–11; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6712–01–P
DEPARTMENT OF THE INTERIOR
Fish and Wildlife Service
50 CFR Part 17
[Docket No. FWS–R4–ES–2011–0043; MO
92210–0–0008]
RIN 1018–AX83
Endangered and Threatened Wildlife
and Plants; Proposed Listing of the
Miami Blue Butterfly as Endangered,
and Proposed Listing of the Cassius
Blue, Ceraunus Blue, and Nickerbean
Blue Butterflies as Threatened Due to
Similarity of Appearance to the Miami
Blue Butterfly
AGENCY: Fish and Wildlife Service,
Interior.
ACTION: Proposed rule; request for
public comments.
SUMMARY: We, the U.S. Fish and
Wildlife Service (Service), propose to
list the Miami blue butterfly (Cyclargus
thomasi bethunebakeri) as endangered
under the Endangered Species Act of
1973, as amended (Act). An emergency
rule listing this subspecies as
endangered for 240 days is published
concurrently in this issue of the Federal
Register. We also propose to list the
cassius blue butterfly (Leptotes cassius
theonus), ceraunus blue butterfly
(Hemiargus ceraunus antibubastus), and
nickerbean blue butterfly (Cyclargus
ammon) as threatened due to similarity
of appearance to the Miami blue, with
a special rule pursuant to section 4(d) of
the Act. We solicit additional data,
information, and comments that may
assist us in making a final decision on
this proposed action.
DATES: Comments from all interested
parties must be received by October 11,
2011. Public hearing requests must be
received by September 26, 2011.
ADDRESSES: You may submit comments
by one of the following methods:
• Federal eRulemaking Portal: https://
www.regulations.gov. Follow the
instructions for submitting comments
on docket number FWS–R4–ES–2011–
0043.
• U.S. mail or hand-delivery: Public
Comments Processing, Attn: FWS–R4–
PO 00000
Frm 00028
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
ES–2011–0043; Division of Policy and
Directives Management; U.S. Fish and
Wildlife Service; 4401 North Fairfax
Drive, MS 2042–PDM; Arlington, VA
22203.
We will post all comments on
https://www.regulations.gov. This
generally means that we will post any
personal information you provide us
(see Public Comments section below for
more information).
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
Paula Halupa, Fish and Wildlife
Biologist, U.S. Fish and Wildlife
Service, South Florida Ecological
Services Office, 1339 20th Street, Vero
Beach, Florida 32960–3559 by
telephone 772–562–3909, ext. 257 or by
electronic mail: miamiblueinfo@fws.gov.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION:
Public Comments Solicited
Our intent is to use the best available
commercial and scientific data as the
foundation for all endangered and
threatened species classification
decisions. Therefore, we request
comments or suggestions from other
concerned governmental agencies, the
scientific community, industry, or any
other interested party concerning this
proposed rule to list the Miami blue
butterfly (Cyclargus thomasi
bethunebakeri) as endangered. We
particularly seek comments concerning:
(1) Biological, commercial trade, or
other relevant data concerning any
threat (or lack thereof) to the Miami blue
butterfly;
(2) The location of any additional
populations of the Miami blue butterfly
within or outside the United States;
(3) Additional information regarding
the taxonomy, genetics, life history (e.g.,
dispersal capabilities, host plants,
nectar sources, dependence on ants),
range, distribution, population size, and
metapopulation dynamics of the Miami
blue;
(4) Current or planned activities in
occupied or potential habitat and their
possible impacts to the Miami blue;
(5) The reasons why any habitat
should or should not be determined to
be critical habitat for the Miami blue as
provided by section 4 of the Act,
including physical and biological
features within areas occupied or
specific areas outside of the geographic
area occupied that are essential for the
conservation of the subspecies;
(6) Threats to the Miami blue butterfly
from collection of or commercial trade
involving the cassius blue butterfly
(Leptotes cassius theonus), ceraunus
blue butterfly (Hemiargus ceraunus
antibubastus), and nickerbean blue
butterfly (Cyclargus ammon), due to the
E:\FR\FM\10AUP1.SGM
10AUP1
Agencies
[Federal Register Volume 76, Number 154 (Wednesday, August 10, 2011)]
[Proposed Rules]
[Pages 49401-49408]
From the Federal Register Online via the Government Printing Office [www.gpo.gov]
[FR Doc No: 2011-20322]
=======================================================================
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION
47 CFR Parts 36, 54, 61, 64, and 69
[WC Docket No. 10-90; DA 11-1348]
Universal Service--Intercarrier Compensation Transformation
AGENCY: Federal Communications Commission.
ACTION: Proposed rule.
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
SUMMARY: In this document, the Federal Communications Commission
(Commission) seeks targeted comment on certain issues in the Universal
Service--Intercarrier Compensation Transformation proceeding. The
Commission has received several proposals in the record in this
proceeding to which we would like to receive comment from interested
parties. This opportunity for additional, targeted comment will
facilitate comprehensive universal service and intercarrier
compensation reform.
DATES: Comments on the Pubic Notice are due on or before August 24,
2011, and reply comments are due on or before August 31, 2011.
ADDRESSES: You may submit comments, identified by WC Docket Nos. 10-90,
07-135, 05-337, 03-109; GN Docket No. 09-51; CC Docket Nos. 01-92, 96-
45, by any of the following methods:
Federal eRulemaking Portal: https://www.regulations.gov.
Follow the instructions for submitting comments.
Federal Communications Commission's Web Site: https://fjallfoss.fcc.gov/ecfs2/. Follow the instructions for submitting
comments.
People with Disabilities: Contact the FCC to request
reasonable accommodations (accessible format documents, sign language
interpreters, CART, etc.) by e-mail: FCC504@fcc.gov or phone: (202)
418-0530 or TTY: (202) 418-0432.
For detailed instructions for submitting comments and additional
information on the notice process, see the SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION
section of this document.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: Katie King, Telecommunications Access
Policy Division, Wireline Competition
[[Page 49402]]
Bureau, (202) 418-7400, Daniel Ball, Pricing Policy Division, Wireline
Competition Bureau, (202) 418-1520 or Sue McNeil, Auctions and Spectrum
Access Division, Wireless Telecommunications Bureau at (202) 418-0660,
or TTY: (202) 418-0484.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: This is a synopsis of the Public Notice in
WC Docket No. 10-90, GN Docket No. 09-51, WC Docket No. 07-135, WC
Docket No. 05-337, CC Docket No. 01-92, CC Docket No. 96-45, and WC
Docket No. 03-109, DA 11-1348 released August 3, 2011. The complete
text of this document is available for inspection and copying during
normal business hours in the FCC Reference Information Center, Portals
II, 445 12th Street, SW., Room CY-A257, Washington, DC 20554. The
document may also be purchased from the Commission's duplicating
contractor, Best Copy and Printing, Inc., 445 12th Street, SW., Room
CY-B402, Washington, DC 20554, telephone (800) 378-3160 or (202) 863-
2893, facsimile (202) 863-2898, or via the Internet at https://www.bcpiweb.com. It is also available on the Commission's Web site at
https://www.fcc.gov.
Pursuant to Sec. Sec. 1.415 and 1.419 of the Commission's rules,
interested parties may file comments and reply comments on or before
the dates indicated on the first page of this document. Comments may be
filed using: (1) The Commission's Electronic Comment Filing System
(ECFS); (2) the Federal Government's eRulemaking Portal; or (3) by
filing paper copies. See Electronic Filing of Documents in Rulemaking
Proceedings, 63 FR 24121, May 1, 1998.
Electronic Filers: Comments may be filed electronically using
the Internet by accessing the ECFS: https://www.fcc.gov/cgb/ecfs/ or the
Federal eRulemaking Portal: https://www.regulations.gov. Filers should
follow the instructions provided on the website for submitting
comments.
[cir] For ECFS filers, if multiple docket or rulemaking numbers
appear in the caption of this proceeding, filers must transmit one
electronic copy of the comments for each docket or rulemaking number
referenced in the caption. In completing the transmittal screen, filers
should include their full name, U.S. Postal Service mailing address,
and the applicable docket or rulemaking number. Parties may also submit
an electronic comment by Internet e-mail. To get filing instructions,
filers should send an e-mail to ecfs@fcc.gov, and include the following
words in the body of the message, ``get form.'' A sample form and
directions will be sent in response.
[cir] Paper Filers: Parties who choose to file by paper must file
an original and four copies of each filing. If more than one docket or
rulemaking number appears in the caption of this proceeding, filers
must submit two additional copies for each additional docket or
rulemaking number.
Filings can be sent by hand or messenger delivery, by
commercial overnight courier, or by first-class or overnight U.S.
Postal Service mail (although we continue to experience delays in
receiving U.S. Postal Service mail). All filings must be addressed to
the Commission's Secretary, Office of the Secretary, Federal
Communications Commission.
[cir] All hand-delivered or messenger-delivered paper filings for
the Commission's Secretary must be delivered to FCC Headquarters at 445
12th St., SW., Room TW-A325, Washington, DC 20554. The filing hours at
this location are 8 a.m. to 7 p.m. All hand deliveries must be held
together with rubber bands or fasteners. Any envelopes must be disposed
of before entering the building.
[cir] Commercial overnight mail (other than U.S. Postal Service
Express Mail and Priority Mail) must be sent to 9300 East Hampton
Drive, Capitol Heights, MD 20743.
[cir] U.S. Postal Service first-class, Express, and Priority mail
should be addressed to 445 12th Street, SW., Washington, DC 20554.
In addition, one copy of each pleading must be sent to the
Commission's duplicating contractor, Best Copy and Printing, Inc, 445
12th Street, SW., Room CY-B402, Washington, DC 20554; Web site: https://www.bcpiweb.com; phone: 1-800-378-3160. Furthermore, one copy of each
pleading must be sent to Charles Tyler, Telecommunications Access
Policy Division, Wireline Competition Bureau, 445 12th Street, SW.,
Room 5-A452, Washington, DC 20554; e-mail: Charles.Tyler@fcc.gov.
Filings and comments are also available for public inspection and
copying during regular business hours at the FCC Reference Information
Center, Portals II, 445 12th Street, SW., Room CY-A257, Washington, DC
20554. Copies may also be purchased from the Commission's duplicating
contractor, BCPI, 445 12th Street, SW., Room CY-B402, Washington, DC
20554. Customers may contact BCPI through its Web site: https://www.bcpiweb.com, by e-mail at fcc@bcpiweb.com, by telephone at (202)
488-5300 or (800) 378-3160 (voice), (202) 488-5562 (tty), or by
facsimile at (202) 488-5563.
To request materials in accessible formats for people with
disabilities (Braille, large print, electronic files, audio format),
send an e-mail to fcc504@fcc.gov or call the Consumer & Governmental
Affairs Bureau at (202) 418-0530 (voice) or (202) 418-0432 (TTY).
Contact the FCC to request reasonable accommodations for filing
comments (accessible format documents, sign language interpreters,
CART, etc.) by e-mail: FCC504@fcc.gov; phone: (202) 418-0530 or TTY:
(202) 418-0432.
This matter shall be treated as a ``permit-but-disclose''
proceeding in accordance with the Commission's ex parte rules. Persons
making oral ex parte presentations are reminded that memoranda
summarizing the presentations must contain summaries of the substance
of the presentation and not merely a listing of the subjects discussed.
More than a one or two sentence description of the views and arguments
presented generally is required. Other rules pertaining to oral and
written ex parte presentations in permit-but-disclose proceedings are
set forth in section 1.1206(b) of the Commission's rules.
Discussion
In order to comprehensively reform and modernize the universal
service fund (USF) and intercarrier compensation (ICC) system in light
of recent technological, market, and regulatory changes, on February 9,
2011, the Commission released the Universal Service and Intercarrier
Compensation Transformation Notice of Proposed Rulemaking (USF-ICC
Transformation NPRM). The NPRM sought public comment on reforms to
modernize USF and ICC for broadband, control the size of the USF as it
transitions to support broadband, require accountability from companies
receiving support, and use market-driven and incentive-based policies
that maximize the value of scarce program resources for the benefit of
consumers. Previously, on October 14, 2010, the Commission released the
Universal Service Reform--Mobility Fund Notice of Proposed Rulemaking
(Mobility Fund NPRM), 75 FR 67060, which proposed to expand mobile
voice and data service availability by using a market-based mechanism
to award one-time support from accumulated USF reserves. In response to
the USF-ICC Transformation NPRM, a number of parties have offered
specific proposals for reform, including a proposal by the State
Members of the Federal-State Universal Service Joint Board (State
Members), the ``RLEC Plan'' put forward by the Joint Rural
Associations, and the ``America's Broadband Connectivity Plan'' filed
by six Price Cap Companies
[[Page 49403]]
(``ABC Plan''). We seek comment on how these proposals comport with the
Commission's articulated objectives and statutory requirements. We
invite comment on specific aspects of the proposals and on additional
issues that are not fully developed in the record.
I. Universal Service
A. Separate Support for Mobile Broadband
Several parties propose that the Commission create two
separate components of the Connect America Fund, one focused on
ensuring that consumers receive fixed voice and broadband service
(which could be wired or wireless) from a single provider of last
resort in areas that are uneconomic to serve with fixed service, and
one focused on providing ongoing support for mobile voice and broadband
service in areas that are uneconomic to serve with mobile service
(i.e., a Mobile Connect America Fund), with the two components together
providing annual support under a defined budget. We seek comment on
providing separate funding for fixed broadband (wired or wireless) and
mobility. How should the Commission set the relative budgets of two
separate components? How should the budgets be revised over time?
In the USF/ICC Transformation NPRM, the Commission sought
comment on phasing down high-cost support for competitive eligible
telecommunications carriers (competitive ETCs) over 5 years and
transitioning such support to the CAF. To what extent would projected
savings associated with intercarrier compensation reform for wireless
carriers as proposed in the ABC Plan help offset reductions in high-
cost support for competitive ETCs? We ask parties to substantiate their
comments with data and remind parties that they may file data under the
protective order issued in this proceeding.
B. Elimination of Rural and Non-Rural Carrier Distinctions
In the USF/ICC Transformation NPRM, the Commission sought
comment on two potential paths for the long term CAF: (1) Use a
competitive, technology-neutral bidding process to determine CAF
recipients; or (2) offer the current voice carrier of last resort a
right of first refusal to serve the area for an amount of ongoing
support determined by a cost model, with a competitive process if the
incumbent refuses the offer. Several parties that jointly filed a
letter proposing a path for reform propose a hybrid system in which
support would be determined under a combination of a forward-looking
cost model and competitive bidding in areas served by price cap
companies, while companies that today are regulated under a rate of
return methodology would continue to receive support based on embedded
costs, albeit with greater accountability and cost controls. Similarly,
the State Members suggest that a forward-looking model be used for
price cap companies, while rate of return companies would have the
option of receiving support under a model or based on embedded costs.
We seek comment on the policy implications of eliminating the current
references to rural and non-rural carriers in our rules and of adopting
two separate approaches to determining support for carriers that
operate in rural areas that are uneconomic to serve, based on whether a
company is regulated under rate of return or price caps in the
interstate jurisdiction.
C. CAF Support for Price Cap Areas
1. Use of a Model.
[cir] Both the State Members and the ABC Plan would use a forward-
looking model to determine support amounts for areas where there is no
private sector business case to offer broadband. We seek comment on
what information would need to be filed in the record regarding the
CostQuest Broadband Analysis Tool (CQBAT model) for the Commission to
consider adopting it, as proposed in the ABC Plan.
[cir] The ABC Plan proposes using one technology to determine the
modeled costs of 4 Mbps download/768 kbps upload service, while
permitting support recipients to use any technology capable of meeting
those requirements. Should the amounts determined by a model be
adjusted to reflect the technology actually deployed? Is ten years an
appropriate time frame for determining support levels, given statutory
requirements for an evolving definition of universal service? Should
the model reflect the costs of building a network capable of meeting
future consumer demand for higher bandwidth that reasonably can be
anticipated five years from now?
2. Right of First Refusal (ROFR).
[cir] The ABC Plan would give an incumbent local exchange carrier
(LEC) the opportunity to accept or decline a model-determined support
amount in a wire center if the incumbent LEC has already made high-
speed Internet service available to more than 35 percent of the service
locations in the wire center. We seek comment on this proposal. Would
aggregating census blocks to something other than a wire center be an
improvement to the proposal? Is 35 percent a reasonable threshold?
Should areas that are overlapped by an unsubsidized facilities-based
provider be excluded when calculating the percentage? Is the
opportunity to exercise a ROFR reasonable consideration for an
incumbent LEC's ongoing responsibility to serve as a voice carrier of
last resort throughout its study areas, even as legacy support flows
are being phased down? Should any ROFR go to the provider with the most
broadband deployment in the relevant area rather than automatically to
the incumbent LEC? Alternatively, if there are at least two providers
in the relevant area that exceed the threshold, should the Commission
use competitive bidding to select the support recipient?
3. Public Interest Obligations.
[cir] Last year, the Federal-State Joint Board on Universal Service
recommended that the Commission adopt a principle ``that universal
service support should be directed where possible to networks that
provide advanced services, as well as voice services.'' If that
recommendation is adopted, how could the CQBAT model be improved to
account for the costs of providing both broadband and voice service?
[cir] The State Members propose that recipients of support meet
specific broadband build-out milestones at years 1, 3 and 5 of
deployment. A company that exceeded a specified minimum standard, but
failed to meet the higher standard at a given milestone would receive a
pro rata share of support. We seek comment on what specific interim
milestones would be effective in ensuring that carriers receiving CAF
support are building out broadband at a reasonable rate during the
specified build-out period.
[cir] The ABC Plan proposes that CAF recipients provide broadband
service that meets specified bandwidth requirements to all locations
within a supported area, but does not address the pricing of such
services or usage allowances. Should the Commission adopt reporting
requirements for supported providers regarding pricing and usage
allowances to facilitate its ability to ensure that consumers in rural
areas are receiving reasonably comparable services at reasonably
comparable rates?
4. Eligible Telecommunications Carrier (ETC) Requirements.
[cir] The ABC Plan proposes a procurement model, in which
recipients of CAF support incur service obligations only to the extent
they agree to perform them in explicit agreements with the Commission,
and CAF recipients are
[[Page 49404]]
free to use any technology, wireline or wireless, that meets specified
bandwidth and service requirements. What specific rule changes to the
Commission's rules, including part 54, subpart C of the Commission's
rules, would be necessary to implement such a proposal?
5. State Role.
[cir] The State Members and other commenters propose an ongoing
role for states in monitoring and oversight over recipients of
universal service support. We seek comment on specific illustrative
areas where the states could work in partnership with the Commission in
advancing universal service, subject to a uniform national framework,
and invite comments on other suggestions. For example:
Were the Commission to adopt a ROFR mechanism, could the
states determine whether a provider has already made a substantial
broadband investment in a particular area, and therefore would be
eligible to be offered support amounts determined under a forward-
looking model?
Should ETCs be required to file copies of all information
submitted to the Commission regarding compliance with public interest
obligations with the states, as well as with USAC?
The ABC Plan contemplates that CAF recipients would serve
all business and residential locations within a supported area, but
does not specifically address the obligation to serve newly built
locations within a supported area over the ten-year term of the
funding. Should states be charged with determining whether any charges
for extending service to newly constructed buildings are reasonable,
based on local conditions?
Should states collect information regarding customer
complaints, including complaints about unfulfilled service requests and
inadequate service?
D. Reforms for Rate-of-Return Carriers
In light of the RLEC Plan and the Joint Letter, as well as
proposals by the State Members, we seek comment below on specific
issues relating to universal service support for rate-of-return
companies.
[cir] Re-examining the Interstate Rate of Return. The Joint Letter
proposes that CAF calculations for areas served by rate-of-return
companies would be calculated using a 10 percent interstate rate of
return. The State Members recommended that the rate of return for
universal service calculations be set at 8.5 percent. We seek comment
on what data the Commission would need to have in the record to enable
it to waive the requirements in part 65 of the Commission's rules for a
rate of return prescription proceeding, so that the Commission could
quickly adopt a particular rate of return.
[cir] Corporate Operations Expense Limitation Formula. We seek
comment on applying the following formula to limit recovery of
corporate operations expenses for high-cost loop support (HCLS),
interstate common line support (ICLS), and local switching support
(LSS).
For study areas with 6,000 or fewer working loops, the monthly
amount per loop shall be limited to;
$42.337-(.00328 x the number of working loops) or $50,000/the number of
working loops, whichever is greater
For study areas with more than 6,000 working loops, but fewer than
17,888 working loops, the monthly amount per loop shall be limited to:
$3.007 + (117,990/number of working loops)
For study areas with 17,888 or more working loops, the monthly
amount per loop shall be limited to:
$9.52 per working loop.
[cir] Eliminating Support for Areas with an Unsubsidized
Competitor. In responding to the NPRM, the RLEC Plan suggested that the
Commission could establish a process to reduce an incumbent's support
if another facilities-based provider proves that it provides sufficient
broadband and voice service to at least 95 percent of the households in
the incumbent's study area without any support or cross-subsidy. We
seek comment on such a process, including how to allocate costs to the
remaining portions of the incumbent's study area for purposes of
determining universal service support. Would a cost model be a way to
allocate costs between the subsidized and unsubsidized portion of a
rate-of-return study area that overlaps substantially with an
unsubsidized competitor? Could state commissions administer proceedings
to consider such challenges, similar to the suggestion in the ABC Plan
that state commissions could elect to determine which census blocks
served by price cap companies have unsubsidized competitors, and
therefore are not eligible for CAF support?
[cir] Limits on Reimbursable Operating and Capital Costs. We seek
comment on limiting reimbursable levels of capital investment and
operating expenses for LSS.
E. Ensuring Consumer Equity
Rate Benchmark. In the USF/ICC Transformation NPRM, the
Commission sought comment on the use of a rate benchmark to encourage
states to rebalance their rates and ensure that universal service does
not subsidize carriers with artificially low rates. In response to the
NPRM, one commenter suggested that we should develop a benchmark for
voice service and reduce a carrier's high-cost support by the amount
that its rate falls below the benchmark. Under such an approach, the
Commission would reduce intrastate universal service support
(specifically, HCLS for rural carriers and high-cost model support
(HCMS) for non-rural carriers) dollar for dollar during the transition
to CAF to the extent the company's local rates do not meet the
specified benchmark. These reductions would not flow to other
recipients. We seek comment on this proposal and proposed variations on
it. Should we set the initial benchmark using the most recently
available data that the Commission has regarding local rates? For
example, according to the 2008 Reference Book of Rates, the average
monthly charge for flat-rate service was $15.62 per month. Using the
same data, the average monthly charge for flat-rate service, plus
subscriber line charges of $5.74 per month, would total $21.36 per
month. Should the benchmark rise over a period of three years, for
instance, with an end point of $25-$30 (or some other amount) for the
total of the local residential rate, federal subscriber line charge
(SLC), state subscriber line charge, mandatory extended area service
charges, and per-line contribution to a state's high cost fund, if one
exists? Should this benchmark be the same as the ICC benchmark?
Total company earnings review. The State Members
recommended that a Provider of Last Resort Fund include a total company
earnings review to limit a supported carrier from earning more than a
reasonable return. We seek to further develop the record on the
mechanics of conducting an earnings review to ensure that universal
service is not providing excessive support to the detriment of
consumers across the United States.
[cir] We seek comment on the State Members' recommendation that, at
least initially, the support mechanism should not factor in either the
revenues or marginal costs of video operations to avoid the risk of
subsidizing video operating losses attributable to unregulated
programming costs.
[cir] We seek comment on what total company rate of return should
be used, what the mechanism should be for reducing support to the
extent that total company rate of return is exceeded, and
[[Page 49405]]
how often a total company earnings review should be conducted.
[cir] We seek comment on what carriers should be required to submit
to USAC, in a standard format, to facilitate a total company earnings
review. For example, should we require submission of the audited
financial statements for the incumbent LEC, a consolidated balance
sheet and income statement for the incumbent LEC and its affiliates, a
list of affiliates, a schedule showing dividends paid to shareholders
or patronage refunds distributed to members of cooperatives for the
last five years, a Cost Allocation Manual, an explanation of how
revenues from bundled services are booked, a trial balance of accounts
at a Class B accounting level or greater, and the number of retail
customers served by the incumbent LEC and its affiliates for voice and
broadband service?
F. Highest-Cost Areas
The ABC Plan would rely on satellite broadband to serve
extremely high-cost areas. We seek comment on a proposal by ViaSat to
create a Competitive Technologies Fund to distribute support through a
combination of a reverse auction and consumer vouchers to enable
consumers in highest-cost areas to obtain service from wireless,
satellite, or other providers.
We also seek comment on what obligations are appropriate
to impose on recipients of funding, as a condition of receiving
support, to facilitate provisioning by others in areas the recipients
are not obligated to serve. For example, Public Knowledge has proposed
to require recipients to make interconnection points and backhaul
capacity available so that unserved high-cost communities could deploy
their own broadband networks. Should recipients' Acceptable Use
Policies also be required to allow customers to share their broadband
connections with unserved customers nearby, for example, through the
use of WiFi combined with directional antenna technology?
G. CAF Support for Alaska, Hawaii, Tribal Lands, U.S. Territories, and
Other Areas
GCI has proposed an Alaska-specific set of universal
service reforms that it asserts better reflect the operating conditions
in Alaska and the lower level of broadband and mobile deployment in
that state. We seek comment on this proposal for Alaska, and ask
whether this, or a similar approach, would also be warranted for
Hawaii, Tribal lands, the U.S. Territories, or other particular areas,
and how we should consider such proposals in light of the Tribal lands
exclusion from the current cap on high-cost support for competitive
ETCs. We further seek comment on other proposals relating to Alaska and
Hawaii that have been proposed in the record. We further seek comment
on how such proposals could be improved, if the Commission were to
adopt a plan to constrain the size of the CAF and access restructuring
within a $4.5 billion annual budget, and whether, in the alternative,
other modifications are warranted to the national policy to better
reflect operating conditions in these areas.
H. Implementing Reform Within a Defined Budget
The ABC Plan recommends a five-year transition for phasing
down legacy funding, concomitant with a phase-in of potential CAF
support, including potential access recovery associated with
intercarrier compensation reform; the Joint Letter suggests several
potential measures that could be taken to keep support totals within a
budget, such as phasing in funding for mobility, deferring CAF funding
for study areas served by particular price cap companies, or deferring
reductions in intercarrier compensation. We seek comment on the
implications of these and alternative proposals, including variations
to the Commission's prior proposals regarding safety net additive (SNA)
and LSS, for ensuring that total funding remains within a defined
budget.
I. Interim Reforms for Price Cap Carriers
As an interim step, Windstream, Frontier and CenturyLink
suggest that the Commission could immediately target support that
currently flows to price cap carriers to the highest-cost wire centers
within their service territories, using a regression analysis based on
the Commission's existing high-cost model to estimate wire center
forward-looking costs for both rural and non-rural price cap carriers.
We seek comment on this proposal and how it relates to other proposals
in the record for comprehensive reform.
[cir] In addition to combining and distributing HCLS and HCMS,
should the Commission also include funds currently provided through LSS
and SNA to price cap carriers? Should we also include funds currently
provided to price cap carriers through interstate access support (IAS)
and frozen ICLS?
[cir] Should the Commission increase annual HCMS support by an
additional amount, such as $100 to $200 million, to be repurposed from
ongoing reductions in support for companies that have chosen to
relinquish universal service funding? Should we impose a cap on the
amount of support a carrier is eligible to receive for a wire center?
For instance, should that cap be set at $250 per line per month,
similar to the Commission's proposal for a cap in total support for all
existing recipients?
[cir] What public interest obligations for using funding for
broadband-capable networks should apply to carriers receiving support
under this approach? Should carriers receiving such support be
prohibited from using the funds in areas that are served by an
unsubsidized facilities-based broadband provider?
[cir] Do any special circumstances exist in the states of Alaska
and Hawaii, or Territories and Tribal lands generally, or other areas,
that warrant a different approach for price cap carriers serving such
areas, if the Commission were to adopt this interim measure?
II. Intercarrier Compensation
A. Federal-State Roles
1. Federal Framework.
The ABC Plan proposes that the Commission set the
framework to reduce intrastate access rates, and recovery to the extent
necessary for those reduced intrastate access revenues would come from
the federal jurisdiction through a combination of federal SLC increases
and federal universal service support.
[cir] How would this aspect of the ABC Plan affect states in
different stages of intrastate access reform--those that have
undertaken significant reform and moved intrastate rates to parity with
interstate rates, those in the process of reform, and states that have
not yet initiated reform?
[cir] The ABC Plan provides a uniform, consistent framework for
reform across all states. We seek comment on whether the ABC Plan could
be improved by providing states incentives to increase artificially low
consumer rates or create state USFs for example through the use of a
consumer monthly rate ceiling or benchmark or by requiring states to
contribute a certain amount per line of recovery to offset intrastate
rate reductions?
In calculating access recovery, the ABC Plan proposes a
$30 ``rate benchmark'' for price cap carriers, and the Rate-of-Return
plan proposes a $25 benchmark, both of which are structured as a
ceiling on consumer rate increases (via a federal SLC), to limit
increases on consumer rates in states where such rates have already
been raised as part of intrastate access reform. Is this ceiling
sufficient to mitigate any
[[Page 49406]]
potential impact on consumers in states that have already begun reforms
(and thus are already paying increased local rates and/or state
universal service contributions associated with such reform) relative
to consumers in states that have not yet undertaken such reforms (for
which all recovery would come through the federal mechanism in the ABC
Plan)? Should there be different rate benchmarks for different carriers
or should there be a single benchmark?
In the ABC Plan, in calculating access recovery, the
initial consumer monthly rate is taken as a snapshot in time as of
January 1, 2012. In lieu of a snapshot, and in order to avoid deterring
states from rebalancing local rates and/or establishing state USFs,
should the rate used to determine access recovery be the ``higher of''
(1) The rate as of January 2012 and (2) the rate at future points
before annual access recovery amounts are calculated? In this scenario,
any increased consumer rates as a result of state reforms, would count
toward the benchmark, more accurately reflecting the actual consumer
burden at that time.
A rate benchmark could also be used as an imputation for a
certain level of end-user recovery for intrastate rate reductions,
rather than as a ceiling on federal SLC increases. For instance, the Ad
Hoc Telecommunications Users Committee proposes a local rate benchmark
that could be imputed, rather than used as a ceiling, and commenters
propose a range of possible benchmarks from $25-$30. Would an
imputation approach better encourage states that currently depend on
long distance consumers to help subsidize local phone service for their
local consumers to bring consumer rates to levels more comparable to
the national average? What would be the appropriate level for such a
benchmark, and should it be phased in over time?
Instead of or in addition to a rate benchmark, should
states be responsible for contributing a certain dollar amount per line
to aid in access recovery? The State Members, for example, suggest that
states contribute $2 per line for purposes of universal service. In
this scenario, a state would be responsible for recovery of $2 per line
of reduced intrastate access revenues, which could be imputed to
carriers before they become eligible for federal recovery. Does this
approach appropriately balance the interests of consumers in states
that already have implemented some reforms, with the associated burden
of reform being born by consumers in those states, rather than federal
recovery mechanisms? If so, should states that already have a state
universal service fund be exempted completely from this per-line
contribution, or only to the extent of, for example, the $2 per line
state contribution to recovery?
2. State-Federal Framework.
In the alternative, the State Members propose that the
states reform intrastate rates and that the Commission facilitate this
reform through state inducements rather than a federal framework. We
seek comment on this proposal.
[cir] To address concerns that some states may not reform
intrastate access charges, we seek comment on a framework, similar to a
proposal in the USF/ICC Transformation NPRM, under which states have
three years to develop an intrastate reform plan. Under this
alternative, after three years, the Commission would set a transition
for reducing intrastate access rates and deny any further federal
recovery to offset reduced intrastate revenue.
[cir] If the Commission adopts the state-federal framework approach
advocated by the State Members, how can the Commission best incent
states to reform intrastate access rates? Should the Commission match
some federal universal service dollars to a state universal service
fund for states that are using such a fund to reform intrastate access
charges? Such matching could be structured in several different ways,
including on a per-line basis (such as $1-2), as a percentage of the
state contribution, or on an aggregate state basis. We seek further
comment on how such a match should be structured to provide adequate
inducements and maintain our commitment to control the size of the
federal high cost fund.
Under the framework of leaving reform of intrastate rates
initially to the states, the Commission would begin immediate reforms
of interstate access charges. We seek comment on a glide path for the
Commission to reduce all interstate access rate elements. Should the
length of the rate transition vary, providing three years for price cap
carriers and five years for rate-of-return carriers, given that rate of
return carriers' interstate access rates are higher at the outset? What
should the transition be for competitive LECs? Would an approach that
provides different transitions for different types of carriers, whether
competitive, price cap or rate-of-return LEC raise any policy concerns?
We also seek comment on whether the Commission should reduce
originating interstate access rates and, if so, whether we should
require the reductions at the same time or only after terminating rates
have been reduced.
B. Scope of Reform
We seek comment on the approach outlined in the ABC Plan
to reform substantially terminating rates for end office switching
while taking a more limited approach to reforming certain transport
elements and originating access. Would any problematic incentives, such
as arbitrage schemes, arise from or be left in place by such an
approach, and if so, what could be done to mitigate them?
C. Recovery Mechanism
We seek comment on the appropriate recovery mechanism for
ICC reform, including the ABC Plan's and the Joint Letter's recovery
proposals. We also seek comment on the relative merits and incentives
for carriers associated with an alternative approach that provides more
predictable recovery amounts, such as the alternative described below.
1. Federal-State Role in Recovery.
[cir] As noted above, the ABC Plan proposes to shift recovery for
reduced intrastate access charge revenues to the federal jurisdiction.
Could the Commission achieve more comprehensive reform of intercarrier
compensation rate elements if recovery is achieved through a federal-
state partnership? We seek comment above on different means by which
states could share responsibility for recovery of reduced intrastate
access revenues.
2. Price Cap Carriers.
[cir] For price cap carriers electing to receive support from the
transitional access replacement mechanism, the ABC Plan's recovery
proposal includes annual true-ups to adjust for possible increases or
decreases in minutes of use. Although minutes of use for incumbent LECs
have been declining, the ABC Plan's proposal establishing how VoIP
minutes are included in the intercarrier compensation system
prospectively and addressing phantom traffic could cause minutes of use
to flatten or possibly even increase. In addition, the ABC Plan would
treat all VoIP traffic as interstate, which potentially could reduce
the minutes billed at intrastate access rates (depending upon existing
payment practices). Thus the true-up approach could result in the need
for additional recovery, including additional federal universal service
funding. We seek comment on alternatives to the true-up process.
[cir] For example, as an alternative to true ups, we seek comment
on a baseline for recovery that would be 2011
[[Page 49407]]
access revenues subject to reform, reduced by 10% annually to account
for decline in demand (i.e., 90% of 2011 revenues in year one (2012),
81.0% in year two (2013), 72.9% in year three (2014), 65.6% in year
four (2015), etc.). This (or a similar framework that may be suggested
by commenters) would be a brightline, predictable approach that would
not include true-ups, regardless of whether demand declines more
quickly or more slowly. If carriers reduce costs or are more efficient,
this approach would enable carriers to realize the benefits of these
savings.
3. Rate of Return Carriers.
[cir] We seek comment below on an alternative approach for recovery
(or other approaches that commenters might suggest) that would maintain
the predictable revenue stream associated with rate of return
principles while also providing carriers with better incentives for
efficient investment and operations. This option would provide a fixed
percentage of recovery (which could be 100%) of all reduced terminating
access charges (both intrastate and interstate) based on year 2011
revenues, but without true-ups to reflect changes in the revenue
requirement historically used for interstate access charges. This
recovery mechanism would lock in revenue streams, including intrastate
access revenues, which have been declining annually for many interstate
rate-of-return carriers. It thus provides more predictable revenue
recovery while also providing incentives for carriers to reduce costs
and realize the benefits of these cost savings. The eligible recovery
amount would be recovered through end-user charges and universal
service support as described in the Joint Letter's proposal. We also
seek comment on the duration of recovery funding under this
alternative. Should it be phased out over time following the completion
of rate reforms, such as with the loss of demand?
4. Reciprocal Compensation.
[cir] The ABC Plan's proposal provides recovery for reductions in
reciprocal compensation rates to the extent they are above $0.0007, but
the ABC Plan estimates on the impact of the federal universal service
fund do not include estimated recovery from reciprocal compensation. We
ask whether providing federal universal service support for reductions
in reciprocal compensation rates strikes the appropriate policy balance
as we seek to control the size of the universal service fund, and
whether there are alternatives to such an approach.
5. Originating Access.
[cir] If the Commission were to address originating access as part
of comprehensive reform, should the Commission treat originating access
revenues differently from terminating access revenues for recovery
purposes since, in many cases, the originating incumbent LEC's
affiliate is offering the long distance service? For example, is it
necessary to provide any recovery for the originating access that an
incumbent LEC historically charged for originating calls from the
retail long distance customers of its affiliate?
[cir] Alternatively, should recovery for such originating access
take the form of a flat per-customer charge imposed on the incumbent
LEC's long distance affiliate for each of its presubscribed customers?
Should such a flat originating access replacement charge be used for
recovery of all originating access revenues more generally? How would
any of these approaches be implemented? Should any flat originating
access replacement charge differ by end-user customer class (such as
residential vs. business), by level of demand, or otherwise?
[cir] We seek the following data to help us evaluate originating
access reform:
Separately for price cap and rate-of-return incumbent
LECs, the number of (1) Long distance minutes that the average customer
originates; (2) 8YY minutes that the average customer originates; and
(3) long distance and 8YY minutes that the average customer receives
(terminating minutes); and
Whether the ratio of originated long distance minutes to
originated 8YY minutes varies materially with the level of the
customers' expenditure on telecommunications services.
D. Impact on Consumers
We seek comment on how to ensure that consumers realize
benefits of reduced long distance and wireless rates as part of
intercarrier compensation reform. The ABC Plan attaches a paper by
Professor Jerry Hausman analyzing the consumer benefits of intercarrier
compensation reform. Should the potential realization of consumer pass
through benefits from intercarrier compensation reform be left to the
market, as Professor Hausman asserts, or should any steps be taken to
ensure that such benefits are realized by consumers? If so, what steps
should be taken?
The ABC Plan permits incumbent carriers to increase the
consumer SLC up to $9.20 before increasing the multiline business SLC,
although multiline business SLCs potentially could increase once
consumer SLCs reach that level. To decrease the potential burden on
consumers and the federal universal service fund, should multiline
business customers also see a modest SLC increase and, if so, how much?
The ABC Plan permits incumbent carriers to increase
consumer SLC rates $0.50-0.75 per year for five years or until the
consumer's rate reaches the rate benchmark of $30. Similarly, the Joint
Letter permits incumbent carriers to increase consumer SLC rates $0.75
per year for six years or until the consumer's rate reaches the rate
benchmark of $25. Professor Hausman's paper indicates that companies
are constrained by competition, which could mean that companies may not
be able to increase SLC rates on consumers. We seek comment on the
actual likely consumer impact of SLC increases, in the aggregate and
with as much granularity (e.g., by company, by type of state, by
specific state) as can be provided. We also seek comment on proposals
that the need for any recovery should be based on the carrier's showing
of need based on its operations more broadly.
We seek the following data to help us quantify consumer
benefits from intercarrier compensation reform:
[cir] If ICC termination rates that currently exceed $0.0007 are
reduced to $0.0007, the services where pass through is likely to occur
(perhaps, for example, long distance, wireless service, 8YY services
and monthly line rentals) and the likely extent of that pass through;
and
[cir] Estimates of demand elasticities for those services where
pass through is likely to occur.
E. VoIP ICC
Implementation. We seek comment on the implementation of
the ABC Plan's proposal for VoIP intercarrier compensation. Under that
proposal, VoIP access traffic would be subject to intercarrier
compensation rates different from rates applied to other access traffic
during the first part of the transition.
[cir] How would VoIP traffic subject to the ICC framework be
identified for purposes of the proposed tariffing regime?
[cir] Would it be feasible to use call record information or
factors or ratios to identify the portion of overall traffic that is
(or reasonably is considered to be) relevant VoIP traffic, perhaps
subject to certification or audits?
[cir] Should the Commission identify a ``safe harbor'' percentage
of VoIP traffic for use in this context? If so, what should be the
factual basis for such a safe harbor? For example, Global Crossing
estimates ``that on average
[[Page 49408]]
roughly fifty to sixty percent of the traffic [on its network] is
VoIP.'' Would that, or other data, provide a basis for a safe harbor?
[cir] Are there alternative mechanisms besides tariffs that could
be used to determine the amount of VoIP traffic exchanged between two
carriers for purposes of the VoIP ICC framework, and if so, what would
be the relative merits of such an approach?
Call Signaling. In the USF/ICC Transformation NPRM the
Commission proposed to apply new call signaling rules designed to
address phantom traffic to telecommunications carriers and
interconnected VoIP providers. Some commenters have expressed concerns
about whether and how the proposed rules would apply to one-way
interconnected VoIP providers. In particular, we seek to further
develop the record regarding possible implementation of any new call
signaling rules that apply to one-way interconnected VoIP providers.
[cir] If call signaling rules apply to one-way interconnected VoIP
providers, how could these requirements be implemented? Would one-way
interconnected VoIP providers be required to obtain and use numbering
resources? If not, how could the new signaling rules operate for
originating callers that do not have a telephone number?
[cir] If one-way interconnected VoIP providers were permitted to
use a number other than an actual North American Numbering Plan (NANP)
telephone number associated with an originating caller in required
signaling, would such use lead to unintended or undesirable
consequences? If so, should other types of carriers or entities also be
entitled to use alternate numbering?
[cir] Would there need to be numbering resources specifically
assigned in the context of one-way VoIP services? Are there other
signaling issues that we should consider with regard to one-way VoIP
calls?
[cir] If call signaling rules were to apply signaling obligations
to one-way interconnected VoIP providers, at what point in a call path
should the required signaling originate, i.e., at the gateway or
elsewhere?
[cir] To what extent are such requirements necessary to implement
the ABC Plan's and Joint Letter's proposals that billing for VoIP
traffic be based on call detail information? More broadly, what
particular call detail information would be used for this purpose? What
are the relative advantages or disadvantages of treating such call
detail information as dispositive for determining whether access
charges or reciprocal compensation rates apply?
Federal Communications Commission.
Marcus Maher,
Deputy Chief, Pricing Policy Division, Wireline Competition Bureau.
[FR Doc. 2011-20322 Filed 8-9-11; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6712-01-P