United States v. Keyspan Corporation; Proposed Final Judgment and Competitive Impact Statement, 9946-9953 [2010-4545]
Download as PDF
9946
Federal Register / Vol. 75, No. 42 / Thursday, March 4, 2010 / Notices
Dist. LEXIS 84787, at *20 (‘‘the ‘public
interest’ is not to be measured by
comparing the violations alleged in the
complaint against those the court
believes could have, or even should
have, been alleged’’). Because the
‘‘court’s authority to review the decree
depends entirely on the government’s
exercising its prosecutorial discretion by
bringing a case in the first place,’’ it
follows that ‘‘the court is only
authorized to review the decree itself,’’
and not to ‘‘effectively redraft the
complaint’’ to inquire into other matters
that the United States did not pursue.
Microsoft, 56 F.3d at 1459–60. As this
Court confirmed in SBC
Communications, courts ‘‘cannot look
beyond the complaint in making the
public interest determination unless the
complaint is drafted so narrowly as to
make a mockery of judicial power.’’ 489
F. Supp. 2d at 15.
In its 2004 amendments to the
Tunney Act,3 Congress made clear its
intent to preserve the practical benefits
of utilizing consent decrees in antitrust
enforcement, stating: ‘‘[n]othing in this
section shall be construed to require the
court to conduct an evidentiary hearing
or to require the court to permit anyone
to intervene.’’ 15 U.S.C. 16(e)(2). The
language wrote into the statute what
Congress intended when it enacted the
Tunney Act in 1974, as Senator Tunney
explained: ‘‘[t]he court is nowhere
compelled to go to trial or to engage in
extended proceedings which might have
the effect of vitiating the benefits of
prompt and less costly settlement
through the consent decree process.’’
119 Cong. Rec. 24,598 (1973) (statement
of Senator Tunney). Rather, the
procedure for the public interest
determination is left to the discretion of
the court, with the recognition that the
court’s ‘‘scope of review remains sharply
proscribed by precedent and the nature
of Tunney Act proceedings.’’ SBC
Commc’ns, 489 F. Supp. 2d at 11.4
mstockstill on DSKH9S0YB1PROD with NOTICES
3 The
2004 amendments substituted the word
‘‘shall’’ for ‘‘may’’ when directing the courts to
consider the enumerated factors and amended the
list of factors to focus on competitive considerations
and address potentially ambiguous judgment terms.
Compare 15 U.S.C. 16(e) (2004), with 15 U.S.C.
16(e)(1) (2006); see also SBC Commc’ns, 489 F.
Supp. 2d at 11 (concluding that the 2004
amendments ‘‘effected minimal changes’’ to Tunney
Act review).
4 See United States v. Enova Corp., 107 F. Supp.
2d 10, 17 (D.D.C. 2000) (noting that the ‘‘Tunney
Act expressly allows the court to make its public
interest determination on the basis of the
competitive impact statement and response to
comments alone’’); United States v. Mid-Am.
Dairymen, Inc., 1977–1 Trade Cas. (CCH) ¶ 61,508,
at 71,980 (W.D. Mo. 1977) (‘‘Absent a showing of
corrupt failure of the government to discharge its
duty, the Court, in making its public interest
finding, should * * * carefully consider the
explanations of the government in the competitive
VerDate Nov<24>2008
16:39 Mar 03, 2010
Jkt 220001
VIII. Determinative Documents
There are no determinative materials
or documents within the meaning of the
APPA that were considered by the
United States in formulating the
proposed Final Judgment.
Dated: February 24, 2010.
Respectfully submitted.
Rachel J. Adcox,
U.S. Department of Justice, Antitrust
Division, Litigation II Section, 450 Fifth
Street, NW., Suite 8700, Washington, DC
20530, (202) 305–2738.
Certificate of Service
I, Rachel J. Adcox, hereby certify that
on February 24, 2010, I caused a copy
of the foregoing Competitive Impact
Statement to be served upon defendants
Bemis Company, Inc., Rio Tinto plc, and
Alcan Corporation by mailing the
documents electronically to the duly
authorized legal representatives of
defendants as follows:
Counsel for Defendant Bemis Company,
Inc.:
Stephen M. Axinn, Esq., John D.
Harkrider, Esq., Axinn, Veltrop &
Harkrider LLP, 114 West 47th
Street, New York, NY 10036, (212)
728–2200, sma@avhlaw.com,
jdh@avhlaw.com.
Counsel for Defendants Rio Tinto plc
and Alcan Corporation:
Steven L. Holley, Esq., Bradley P.
Smith, Esq., Sullivan & Cromwell
LLP, 125 Broad Street, New York,
NY 10004, (212) 558–4737,
holleys@sullcrom.com,
smithbr@sullcrom.com.
Rachel J. Adcox, Esq.,
United States Department of Justice,
Antitrust Division, Litigation II Section, 450
Fifth Street, NW., Suite 8700, Washington,
DC 20530, (202) 616–3302.
[FR Doc. 2010–4550 Filed 3–3–10; 8:45 am]
Patricia A. Brink,
Deputy Director of Operations and Civil
Enforcement.
BILLING CODE P
DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE
United States District Court for the
Southern District of New York
Antitrust Division
United States v. Keyspan Corporation;
Proposed Final Judgment and
Competitive Impact Statement
Notice is hereby given pursuant to the
Antitrust Procedures and Penalties Act,
15 U.S.C. 16(b)–(h), that a proposed
Final Judgment, Stipulation and
Competitive Impact Statement have
impact statement and its responses to comments in
order to determine whether those explanations are
reasonable under the circumstances.’’); S. Rep. No.
93–298, 93d Cong., 1st Sess., at 6 (1973) (‘‘Where
the public interest can be meaningfully evaluated
simply on the basis of briefs and oral arguments,
that is the approach that should be utilized.’’).
PO 00000
Frm 00080
been filed with the United States
District Court for the Southern District
of New York in United States of
America v. KeySpan Corp., Civil Case
No. 10–CIV–1415. On February 22,
2010, the United States filed a
Complaint alleging that KeySpan
Corporation (‘‘KeySpan’’) entered into an
agreement with a financial services
company, the likely effect of which was
to increase prices in the New York City
(NYISO Zone J) Capacity Market, in
violation of Section 1 of the Sherman
Act, 15 U.S.C. 1. The proposed Final
Judgment, filed the same time as the
Complaint, requires KeySpan to pay the
government $12 million dollars.
Copies of the Complaint, proposed
Final Judgment and Competitive Impact
Statement are available for inspection at
the Department of Justice, Antitrust
Division, Antitrust Documents Group,
450 Fifth Street, NW., Suite 1010,
Washington, DC 20530 (telephone: 202–
514–2481), on the Department of
Justice’s Web site at https://
www.justice.gov/atr, and at the Office of
the Clerk of the United States District
Court for the Southern District of New
York. Copies of these materials may be
obtained from the Antitrust Division
upon request and payment of the
copying fee set by Department of Justice
regulations.
Public comment is invited within 60
days of the date of this notice. Such
comments, and responses thereto, will
be published in the Federal Register
and filed with the Court. Comments
should be directed to Donna N.
Kooperstein, Chief, Transportation,
Energy, and Agriculture Section,
Antitrust Division, U.S. Department of
Justice, 450 Fifth Street, NW., Suite
8000, Washington, DC 20530
(telephone: 202–307–6349).
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
Civil Action No.: 10–cv–1415 (WHP)
ECF CASE
United States of America, U.S. Department
of Justice, Antitrust Division, 450 5th Street,
NW., Suite 8000, Washington, DC 20530,
Plaintiff, v. Keyspan Corporation, 1
Metrotech Center, Brooklyn, NY 11201,
Defendant.
Received: February 22, 2010
Complaint
The United States of America, acting
under the direction of the Attorney
General of the United States, brings this
civil antitrust action under Section 4 of
the Sherman Act, as amended, 15 U.S.C.
E:\FR\FM\04MRN1.SGM
04MRN1
Federal Register / Vol. 75, No. 42 / Thursday, March 4, 2010 / Notices
mstockstill on DSKH9S0YB1PROD with NOTICES
4, to obtain equitable and other relief
from defendant’s violation of Section 1
of the Sherman Act, as amended, 15
U.S.C. 1.
On January 18, 2006, KeySpan
Corporation (‘‘KeySpan’’) and a financial
services company executed an
agreement (the ‘‘Keyspan Swap’’) that
ensured that KeySpan would withhold
substantial output from the New York
City electricity generating capacity
market, a market that was created to
ensure the supply of sufficient
generation capacity for New York City
consumers of electricity. The likely
effect of the Keyspan Swap was to
increase capacity prices for the retail
electricity suppliers who must purchase
capacity, and, in turn, to increase the
prices consumers pay for electricity.
I. Introduction
1. Between 2003 and 2006, KeySpan,
the largest seller of electricity generating
capacity (‘‘installed capacity’’) in the
New York City market, earned
substantial revenues due to tight supply
conditions. Because purchasers of
capacity required almost all of
KeySpan’s output to meet expected
demand, KeySpan’s ability to set price
levels was limited only by a regulatory
ceiling (called a ‘‘bid cap’’). Indeed, the
market price for capacity was
consistently at or near KeySpan’s bid
cap, with KeySpan sacrificing sales on
only a small fraction of its capacity.
2. But market conditions were about
to change. Two large, new electricity
generation plants were slated to come
on line in 2006 (with no exit expected
until at least 2009), breaking the
capacity shortage that had kept prices at
the capped levels.
3. KeySpan could prevent the new
capacity from lowering prices by
withholding a substantial amount of its
own capacity from the market. This ‘‘bid
the cap’’ strategy would keep market
prices high, but at a significant cost—
the sacrificed sales would reduce
KeySpan’s revenues by as much as $90
million a year. Alternatively, KeySpan
could compete with its rivals for sales
by bidding more capacity at lower
prices. This ‘‘competitive strategy’’ could
earn KeySpan more than bidding its
cap, but it carried a risk—KeySpan’s
competitors could undercut its price
and take sales away, making the strategy
less profitable than ‘‘bidding the cap.’’
4. KeySpan searched for a way to
avoid both the revenue decline from
bidding its cap and the revenue risks of
competitive bidding. It decided to enter
an agreement that gave it a financial
interest in the capacity of Astoria—
KeySpan’s largest competitor. By
providing KeySpan revenues on a larger
VerDate Nov<24>2008
16:39 Mar 03, 2010
Jkt 220001
base of sales, such an agreement would
make a ‘‘bid the cap’’ strategy more
profitable than a successful competitive
bid strategy. Rather than directly
approach its competitor, KeySpan
turned to a financial services company
to act as the counterparty to the
agreement—the KeySpan Swap—
recognizing that the financial services
company would, and in fact did, enter
an offsetting agreement with Astoria
(the ‘‘Astoria Hedge’’).
5. With KeySpan deriving revenues
from both its own and Astoria’s
capacity, the KeySpan Swap removed
any incentive for KeySpan to bid
competitively, locking it into bidding its
cap. Capacity prices remained as high as
if no entry had occurred.
II. Defendant
6. KeySpan Corporation is a New
York corporation with its principal
place of business in New York City.
During the relevant period of the
allegations in this Complaint, KeySpan
owned approximately 2,400 megawatts
of electricity generating capacity at its
Ravenswood electrical generation
facility, which is located in New York
City. KeySpan had revenues of
approximately $850 million in 2006 and
$700 million in 2007 from the sale of
energy and capacity at its Ravenswood
facility.
III. Jurisdiction and Venue
7. The United States files this
complaint under Section 4 of the
Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. 4, seeking
equitable relief from defendant’s
violation of Section 1 of the Sherman
Act, 15 U.S.C. 1.
8. This court has jurisdiction over this
matter pursuant to 15 U.S.C. 4 and 28
U.S.C. 1331 and 1337.
9. Defendant waives any objection to
venue and personal jurisdiction in this
judicial district for the purpose of this
Complaint.
10. Defendant engaged in interstate
commerce during the relevant period of
the allegations in this Complaint;
KeySpan’s electric generating units
interconnected with generating units
across the country, and KeySpan
regularly sold electricity to customers
outside New York.
11. One generation facility located in
New Jersey supplies capacity to the New
York City installed capacity market.
IV. The New York City Installed
Capacity Market
12. Sellers of retail electricity must
purchase a product from generators
known as ‘‘installed capacity.’’ Installed
capacity is a product created by the New
York Independent System Operator
PO 00000
Frm 00081
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
9947
(‘‘NYISO’’) to ensure that sufficient
generation capacity exists to meet
expected electricity needs. Companies
selling electricity to consumers in New
York City are required to make installed
capacity payments that relate to their
expected peak demand plus a share of
reserve capacity (to cover extra facilities
needed in case a generating facility
breaks down). These payments assure
that retail electric companies do not sell
more electricity than the system can
deliver and also encourage electric
generating companies to build new
facilities as needed.
13. The price for installed capacity
has been set through auctions
administered by the NYISO. The rules
under which these auctions are
conducted have changed from time to
time. Unless otherwise noted, the
description of the installed capacity
market in the following paragraphs
relates to the period May 2003 through
March 2008.
14. Because transmission constraints
limit the amount of energy that can be
imported into the New York City area
from the power grid, the NYISO requires
retail providers of electricity to
customers in New York City to purchase
80% of their capacity from generators in
that region. The NYISO operates
separate capacity auctions for the New
York City region (also known as ‘‘InCity’’ and ‘‘Zone J’’). The NYISO
organizes the auctions to serve two
distinct seasonal periods, summer (May
through October) and winter (November
through April). For each season, the
NYISO conducts seasonal, monthly and
spot auctions in which capacity can be
acquired for all or some of the seasonal
period.
15. In each of the types of auctions,
capacity suppliers offer price and
quantity bids. Supplier bids are
‘‘stacked’’ from lowest-priced to highest,
and compared to the total amount of
demand being satisfied in the auction.
The offering price of the last bid in the
‘‘stack’’ needed to meet requisite
demand establishes the market price for
all capacity bid into that auction.
Capacity bid at higher than this price is
unsold, as is any excess capacity bid at
what becomes the market price.
16. The New York City Installed
Capacity (‘‘NYC Capacity’’) Market
constitutes a relevant geographic and
product market.
17. The NYC Capacity Market is
highly concentrated, with three firms—
KeySpan, NRG Energy, Inc. (‘‘NRG’’) and
Astoria Generating Company (a joint
venture of Madison Dearborn Partners,
LLC and US Power Generating
Company, which purchased the Astoria
generating assets from Reliant Energy,
E:\FR\FM\04MRN1.SGM
04MRN1
9948
Federal Register / Vol. 75, No. 42 / Thursday, March 4, 2010 / Notices
mstockstill on DSKH9S0YB1PROD with NOTICES
Inc. in February 2006)—controlling a
substantial portion of generating
capacity in the market. Because
purchasers of capacity require at least
some of each of these three suppliers’
output to meet expected demand, the
firms are subject to a bid and price cap
for nearly all of their generating capacity
in New York City and are not allowed
to sell that capacity outside of the
NYISO auction process. The NYISO-set
bid cap for KeySpan is the highest of the
three firms, followed by NRG and
Astoria.
18. KeySpan possessed market power
in the NYC Capacity Market.
19. It is difficult and time-consuming
to build or expand generating facilities
within the NYC Capacity Market given
limited undeveloped space for building
or expanding generating facilities and
extensive regulatory obligations.
V. Keyspan’s Plan To Avoid
Competition
20. From June 2003 through December
2005, KeySpan set the market price in
the New York City spot auction by
bidding its capacity at its cap. Given
extremely tight supply and demand
conditions, KeySpan needed to
withhold only a small amount of
capacity to ensure that the market
cleared at its cap.
21. KeySpan anticipated that the tight
supply and demand conditions in the
NYC Capacity Market would change in
2006, due to the entry of approximately
1000 MW of new generation. Because of
the addition of this new capacity,
KeySpan would have to withhold
significantly more capacity from the
market and would earn substantially
lower revenues if it continued to bid all
of its capacity at its bid cap. KeySpan
anticipated that demand growth and
retirement of old generation units would
restore tight supply and demand
conditions in 2009.
22. KeySpan could no longer be
confident that ‘‘bidding the cap’’ would
remain its best strategy during the 2006–
2009 period. It considered various
competitive bidding strategies under
which KeySpan would compete with its
rivals for sales by bidding more capacity
at lower prices. These strategies could
potentially produce much higher
returns for KeySpan but carried the risk
that competitors would undercut its
price and take sales away, making the
strategy less profitable than ‘‘bidding the
cap.’’
23. KeySpan also considered
acquiring Astoria’s generating assets,
which were for sale. This would have
solved the problem that new entry
posed for KeySpan’s revenue stream, as
Astoria’s capacity would have provided
VerDate Nov<24>2008
16:39 Mar 03, 2010
Jkt 220001
KeySpan with sufficient additional
revenues to make continuing to ‘‘bid the
cap’’ its best strategy. KeySpan
consulted with a financial services
company about acquiring the assets. But
KeySpan soon concluded that its
acquisition of its largest competitor
would raise serious market power
issues.
24. Instead of purchasing the Astoria
assets, KeySpan decided to acquire a
financial interest in substantially all of
Astoria’s capacity. KeySpan would pay
Astoria’s owner a fixed revenue stream
in return for the revenues generated
from Astoria’s capacity sales in the
auctions.
25. KeySpan did not approach Astoria
directly and instead sought a
counterparty to enter into a financial
agreement providing KeySpan with
payments derived from the market
clearing price for an amount of capacity
essentially equivalent to what Astoria
owned. KeySpan recognized the
counterparty would need
simultaneously to enter into an
agreement with another capacity
supplier that would offset the
counterparty’s payments to KeySpan,
and KeySpan knew that Astoria was the
only supplier with sufficient capacity to
do so. KeySpan turned to the same
financial services company that it had
consulted about the potential
acquisition of Astoria’s assets. The
financial services company agreed to
serve as the counterparty but, as
expected, informed KeySpan that the
agreement was contingent on the
financial services company also entering
into an offsetting agreement with the
owner of the Astoria generating assets.
VI. The Agreements
26. On or about January 9, 2006,
KeySpan and the financial services
company finalized the terms of the
KeySpan Swap. Under the agreement, if
the market price for capacity was above
$7.57 per kW-month, the financial
services company would pay KeySpan
the difference between the market price
and $7.57 times 1800 MW; if the market
price was below $7.57, KeySpan would
pay the financial services company the
difference times 1800 MW.
27. The KeySpan Swap was executed
on January 18, 2006. The term of the
KeySpan Swap ran from May 2006
through April 2009.
28. On or about January 9, 2006, the
financial services company and Astoria
finalized the terms of the Astoria Hedge.
Under that agreement, if the market
price for capacity was above $7.07 per
kW-month, Astoria would pay the
financial services company the
difference times 1800 MW; if the market
PO 00000
Frm 00082
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
price was below $7.07, Astoria would be
paid the difference times 1800 MW.
29. The Astoria Hedge was executed
on January 11, 2006. The term of the
Astoria Hedge ran from May 2006
through April 2009, matching the
duration of the KeySpan Swap.
VII. The Competitive Effect of the
Keyspan Swap
30. The clear tendency of the
KeySpan Swap was to alter KeySpan’s
bidding in the NYC Capacity Market
auctions.
31. Without the Swap, KeySpan likely
would have chosen from a range of
potentially profitable competitive
strategies in response to the entry of
new capacity. Had it done so, the price
of capacity would have declined. By
transferring a financial interest in
Astoria’s capacity to KeySpan, however,
the Swap effectively eliminated
KeySpan’s incentive to compete for
sales in the same way a purchase of
Astoria or a direct agreement between
KeySpan and Astoria would have done.
By providing KeySpan revenues from
Astoria’s capacity, in addition to
Keyspan’s own revenues, the Swap
made bidding the cap KeySpan’s most
profitable strategy regardless of its
rivals’ bids.
32. After the KeySpan Swap went into
effect in May 2006, KeySpan
consistently bid its capacity at its cap
even though a significant portion of its
capacity went unsold. Despite the
addition of significant new generating
capacity in New York City, the market
price of capacity did not decline.
33. In August 2007, the State of New
York conditioned the sale of KeySpan to
a new owner on the divestiture of
KeySpan’s Ravenswood generating
assets and required KeySpan to bid its
New York City capacity at zero from
March 2008 until the divestiture was
completed. Since March 2008, the
market price for capacity has declined.
34. But for the KeySpan Swap,
installed capacity likely would have
been procured at a lower price in New
York City from May 2006 through
February 2008.
35. The KeySpan Swap produced no
countervailing efficiencies.
VIII. Violation Alleged
36. Plaintiff incorporates the
allegations of paragraphs 1 through 35
above.
37. KeySpan entered into an
agreement the likely effect of which has
been to increase prices in the NYC
Capacity Market, in violation of Section
1 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. 1.
E:\FR\FM\04MRN1.SGM
04MRN1
Federal Register / Vol. 75, No. 42 / Thursday, March 4, 2010 / Notices
IX. Prayer for Relief
Wherefore, Plaintiff prays:
1. That the Court adjudge and decree
that the KeySpan Swap agreement
constitutes an illegal restraint in the sale
of installed capacity in the New York
City market in violation of Section 1 of
the Sherman Act;
2. That plaintiff shall have such other
relief, including equitable monetary
relief, as the nature of this case may
require and as is just and proper to
prevent the recurrence of the alleged
violation and to dissipate the
anticompetitive effects of the violation;
and
3. That plaintiff recover the costs of
this action.
Dated this 22nd day of February 2010.
Respectfully Submitted,
Christine A. Varney,
Assistant Attorney General.
Molly S. Boast,
Deputy Assistant Attorney General.
William F. Cavanaugh, Jr.,
Deputy Assistant Attorney General.
Donna N. Kooperstein,
Chief.
William H. Stalling,
Assistant Chief.
Transportation, Energy & Agriculture Section
Suite 8000.
Patricia A. Brink,
Deputy Director of Operations.
Jade Alice Eaton,
J. Richard Doidge,
John W. Elias,
Trial Attorneys.
U.S. Department of Justice, Antitrust
Division, Transportation, Energy &
Agriculture Section, 450 5th Street, NW.,
Suite 8000, Washington, DC 20530,
Telephone: (202) 353–1560, Facismilie (202)
616–2441, jade.eaton@usdoj.gov.
United States District Court for the
Southern District of New York
ECF Case
mstockstill on DSKH9S0YB1PROD with NOTICES
Civil Action No. 10–cv–1415 (WHP)
United States of America, Plaintiff, v.
Keyspan Corporation, Defendant.
Received: February 22, 2010
Final Judgment
Whereas plaintiff United States of
America filed its Complaint alleging
that Defendant KeySpan Corporation
(‘‘KeySpan’’) violated Section 1 of the
Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. 1, and plaintiff
and KeySpan, through their respective
attorneys, having consented to the entry
of this Final Judgment without trial or
adjudication of any issue of fact or law,
for settlement purposes only, and
without this Final Judgment
constituting any evidence against or an
admission by KeySpan with respect to
any allegation contained in the
Complaint:
VerDate Nov<24>2008
16:39 Mar 03, 2010
Jkt 220001
9949
Now, therefore, before the taking of
any testimony and without trial or
adjudication of any issue of fact or law
herein, and upon the consent of the
parties hereto, it is hereby ordered,
adjudged, and decreed:
Dated:
United States District Judge.
1. Jurisdiction
This Court has jurisdiction of the
subject matter herein and of each of the
parties consenting hereto. The
Complaint states a claim upon which
relief may be granted against KeySpan
under Sections 1 and 4 of the Sherman
Act, 15 U.S.C. 1 and 4.
Civil Action No. 10–cv–1415 (WHP)
United States of America, Plaintiff, v.
Keyspan Corporation, Defendant.
Filed 02/23/2010
2. Applicability
This Final Judgment applies to
KeySpan and each of its successors,
assigns, and to all other persons in
active concert or participation with it
who shall have received actual notice of
the Settlement Agreement and Order by
personal service or otherwise.
3. Relief
A. Within thirty (30) days of the entry
of this Final Judgment, KeySpan shall
pay to the United States the sum of
twelve million dollars ($12,000,000.00).
B. The payment specified above shall
be made by wire transfer. Before making
the transfer, KeySpan shall contact Janie
Ingalls, of the Antitrust Division’s
Antitrust Documents Group, at (202)
514–2481 for wire transfer instructions.
C. In the event of a default in
payment, interest at the rate of eighteen
(18) percent per annum shall accrue
thereon from the date of default to the
date of payment.
4. Retention of Jurisdiction
This Court retains jurisdiction to
enable any party to this Final Judgment
to apply to this Court at any time for
further orders and directions as may be
necessary or appropriate to carry out or
construe this Final Judgment, to modify
any of its provisions, to enforce
compliance, and to punish violations of
its provisions.
5. Public Interest Determination
Entry of this Final Judgment is in the
public interest. The parties have
complied with the requirements of the
Antitrust Procedures and Penalties Act,
15 U.S.C. 16, including making copies
available to the public of this Final
Judgment, the Competitive Impact
Statement, and any comments thereon
and plaintiff’s responses to comments.
Based upon the record before the Court,
which includes the Competitive Impact
Statement and any comments and
response to comments filed with the
Court, entry of this Final Judgment is in
the public interest.
PO 00000
Frm 00083
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
United States District Court for the
Southern District of New York
ECF Case
Competitive Impact Statement
Plaintiff United States of America
(‘‘United States’’), pursuant to Section
2(b) of the Antitrust Procedures and
Penalties Act (‘‘APPA’’ or ‘‘Tunney Act’’),
15 U.S.C. 16(b)–(h), files this
Competitive Impact Statement relating
to the proposed Final Judgment
submitted for entry in this civil antitrust
proceeding.
I. Nature and Purpose of the
Proceedings
The United States brought this
lawsuit against Defendant KeySpan
Corporation (‘‘KeySpan’’) on February
22, 2010, to remedy a violation of
Section 1 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C.
1. On January 18, 2006, KeySpan
entered into an agreement in the form of
a financial derivative (the ‘‘KeySpan
Swap’’) essentially transferring to
KeySpan, the largest supplier of
electricity generating capacity in the
New York City market, the capacity of
its largest competitor. The KeySpan
Swap ensured that KeySpan would
withhold substantial output from the
capacity market, a market that was
created to ensure the supply of
sufficient generation capacity for the
millions of New York City consumers of
electricity. The likely effect of this
agreement was to increase capacity
prices for the retail electricity suppliers
who must purchase capacity, and, in
turn, to increase the prices consumers
pay for electricity.
The proposed Final Judgment
remedies this violation by requiring
KeySpan to disgorge profits obtained
through the anticompetitive agreement.
Under the terms of the proposed Final
Judgment, KeySpan will surrender $12
million to the Treasury of the United
States. Disgorgement will deter KeySpan
and others from future violations of the
antitrust laws.
The United States and KeySpan have
stipulated that the proposed Final
Judgment may be entered after
compliance with the APPA, unless the
United States withdraws its consent.
Entry of the proposed Final Judgment
would terminate this action, except that
this Court would retain jurisdiction to
construe, modify, and enforce the
E:\FR\FM\04MRN1.SGM
04MRN1
9950
Federal Register / Vol. 75, No. 42 / Thursday, March 4, 2010 / Notices
proposed Final Judgment and to punish
violations thereof.
II. Description of the Events Giving Rise
to the Alleged Violation of the Antitrust
Laws
mstockstill on DSKH9S0YB1PROD with NOTICES
A. The Defendant
KeySpan Corporation is a New York
corporation with its principal place of
business in New York City. During the
relevant period of the allegations in this
Complaint, KeySpan owned
approximately 2400 megawatts of
electricity generating capacity at its
Ravenswood electrical generation
facility, which is located in New York
City. KeySpan had revenues of
approximately $850 million in 2006 and
$700 million in 2007 from the sale of
energy and capacity at its Ravenswood
facility.
B. The Market
In the state of New York, sellers of
retail electricity must purchase a
product from generators known as
installed capacity (‘‘capacity’’).1
Electricity retailers are required to
purchase capacity in an amount equal to
their expected peak energy demand plus
a share of reserve capacity. These
payments assure that retail electric
companies do not use more electricity
than the system can deliver and
encourage electric generating companies
to build new facilities as needed.
Because transmission constraints limit
the amount of energy that can be
imported into the New York City area
from the power grid, the New York
Independent System Operator
(‘‘NYISO’’) requires retail providers of
electricity to customers in New York
City to purchase 80% of their capacity
from generators in that region. Thus, the
New York City Installed Capacity (‘‘NYC
Capacity’’) Market constitutes a relevant
geographic and product market.
The price for installed capacity has
been set through auctions administered
by the NYISO. The NYISO organizes the
auctions to serve two distinct seasonal
periods, summer (May though October)
and winter (November through April).
For each season, the NYISO conducts
seasonal, monthly, and spot auctions in
which capacity can be acquired for all
or some of the seasonal period. Capacity
suppliers offer price and quantity bids
in each of these three auctions. Supplier
bids are ‘‘stacked’’ from lowest-priced to
highest. The stack is then compared to
the amount of demand. The offering
price of the last bid in the ‘‘stack’’
needed to meet requisite demand
1 Except where noted otherwise, this description
pertains to the market conditions that existed from
May 2003 through March 2008.
VerDate Nov<24>2008
16:39 Mar 03, 2010
Jkt 220001
establishes the market price for all
capacity sold into that auction. Any
capacity bid at higher than this price is
unsold, as is any excess capacity bid at
what becomes the market price.
The NYC Capacity Market was highly
concentrated during the relevant period,
with three firms—Astoria, NRG Energy,
Inc., and KeySpan—controlling a
substantial portion of the market’s
generating capacity. These three were
designated as pivotal suppliers by the
Federal Energy Regulatory Commission,
meaning that at least some of each of
these three suppliers’ output was
required to satisfy demand. The three
firms were subject to bid and price
caps—KeySpan’s being the highest—for
nearly all of their generating capacity in
New York City and were not allowed to
sell their capacity outside of the NYISO
auction process.
C. The Alleged Violation
1. KeySpan Assesses Plans for Changed
Market Conditions
From June 2003 through December
2005, almost all installed capacity in the
market was needed to meet demand.
With these tight market conditions,
KeySpan could sell almost all of its
capacity into the market, even while
bidding at its cap. KeySpan did so, and
the market cleared at the price
established by the cap, with only a
small fraction of KeySpan’s capacity
remaining unsold.
KeySpan anticipated that the tight
supply and demand conditions in the
NYC Capacity Market would end in
2006 due to the entry into the market of
approximately 1000 MW of generation
capacity, and would not return until
2009 with the retirement of old
generation units and demand growth.
KeySpan could no longer be confident
that ‘‘bid the cap’’ would remain its best
strategy during the 2006–2009 period.
The ‘‘bid the cap’’ strategy would keep
market prices high, but at a significant
cost. KeySpan would have to withhold
a significant additional amount of
capacity to account for the new entry.
The additional withholding would
reduce KeySpan’s revenues by as much
as $90 million a year. Alternatively,
KeySpan could compete with its rivals
for sales by bidding more capacity at
lower prices. KeySpan considered
various competitive bidding strategies.
These could potentially produce much
higher returns for KeySpan than bidding
the cap but carried the risk that
competitors would undercut its price
and take sales away, making the strategy
potentially less profitable than bidding
the cap.
PO 00000
Frm 00084
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
KeySpan also considered acquiring
Astoria’s generating assets, which were
for sale. This would have solved the
problem that new entry posed for
KeySpan’s revenue stream, as Astoria’s
capacity would have provided KeySpan
with sufficient additional revenues to
make continuing to bid its cap its best
strategy. KeySpan consulted with a
financial services company about
acquiring the assets, but soon concluded
that its acquisition of its largest
competitor would raise market power
issues.
2. KeySpan Pursues an Anticompetitive
and Unlawful Agreement
Instead of purchasing the Astoria
assets, KeySpan decided to acquire a
financial interest in Astoria’s capacity.
KeySpan would pay Astoria’s owner a
fixed revenue stream in return for the
revenues generated from Astoria’s
capacity sales in the auctions. The
competitive effect of doing so would be
similar to that of actually purchasing
Astoria’s capacity.
KeySpan did not approach Astoria
directly and instead sought a
counterparty to enter into a financial
agreement providing KeySpan with
payments derived from the market
clearing price for an amount of capacity
essentially equivalent to what Astoria
owned. KeySpan recognized the
counterparty would need
simultaneously to enter into an
agreement with another capacity
supplier that would offset the
counterparty’s payments to Keyspan,
and KeySpan knew that Astoria was the
only supplier with sufficient capacity to
do so. KeySpan turned to the same
financial services company that it had
consulted about the potential
acquisition of Astoria’s assets. The
financial services company agreed to
serve as the counterparty, but, as
expected, informed KeySpan that the
agreement was contingent on the
financial services company also entering
into an offsetting agreement with the
owner of the Astoria generating assets
(the ‘‘Astoria Hedge’’).
On or about January 9, 2006, KeySpan
and the financial services company
finalized the terms of the KeySpan
Swap. Under the agreement, if the
market price for capacity was above
$7.57 per kW-month, the financial
services company would pay KeySpan
the difference between the market price
and $7.57 times 1800 MW; if the market
price was below $7.57, KeySpan would
pay the financial services company the
difference times 1800 MW. The
KeySpan Swap was executed on January
18, 2006. The term of the KeySpan
E:\FR\FM\04MRN1.SGM
04MRN1
Federal Register / Vol. 75, No. 42 / Thursday, March 4, 2010 / Notices
Swap ran from May 2006 through April
2009.
On or about January 9, 2006, the
financial services company and Astoria
finalized terms to the Astoria Hedge.
Under that agreement, if the market
price for capacity was above $7.07 per
kW-month, Astoria would pay the
financial services company the
difference times 1800 MW; if the market
price was below $7.07, Astoria would be
paid the difference times 1800 MW. The
Astoria Hedge was executed on January
11, 2006. The term of the Astoria Hedge
ran from May 2006 through April 2009,
matching the duration of the KeySpan
Swap.
3. The Effect of the KeySpan Swap
The clear tendency of the KeySpan
Swap was to alter KeySpan’s bidding in
the NYC Capacity Market auctions.
Without the swap, KeySpan likely
would have chosen from a range of
potentially profitable competitive
strategies in response to the entry of
new capacity and, had it done so, the
price of capacity would have declined.
The swap, however, effectively
eliminated KeySpan’s incentive to
compete for sales. By adding revenues
from Astoria’s capacity to KeySpan’s
own, the KeySpan Swap made bidding
the cap KeySpan’s most profitable
strategy regardless of its rivals’ bids.
After the KeySpan Swap went into
effect in May 2006, KeySpan
consistently bid its capacity into the
capacity auctions at its cap even though
a significant portion of its capacity went
unsold. Despite the addition of
significant new generating capacity in
New York City, the market price of
capacity did not decline.
By transferring a financial interest in
Astoria’s capacity to KeySpan, the Swap
effectively eliminated KeySpan’s
incentive to compete for sales in the
same way a purchase of Astoria or a
direct agreement between KeySpan and
Astoria would have done. But for the
Swap, installed capacity likely would
have been procured at a lower price in
New York City from May 2006 through
February 2008.2 The Swap produced no
countervailing efficiencies.
mstockstill on DSKH9S0YB1PROD with NOTICES
2 The
effects of the swap continued until March
2008, at which time changes in regulatory
conditions eliminated KeySpan’s ability to affect
the market price. KeySpan was sold to another
company in August 2007. The State of New York
conditioned its approval of the acquisition on the
divestiture of KeySpan’s Ravenswood generating
assets and required KeySpan to bid its New York
City capacity at zero from March 2008 until the
divestiture was completed. Since then, the market
price for capacity has declined.
VerDate Nov<24>2008
16:39 Mar 03, 2010
Jkt 220001
III. Explanation of the Proposed Final
Judgment
The proposed Final Judgment requires
KeySpan to disgorge profits gained as a
result of its unlawful agreement
restraining trade. KeySpan is to
surrender $12 million to the Treasury of
the United States.
A. Disgorgement Is Available Under the
Sherman Act
Although the Antitrust Division has
not previously sought disgorgement as a
remedy under the Sherman Act, district
courts have the authority to order such
equitable relief. The Supreme Court has
held that ‘‘[u]nless a statute in so many
words, or by a necessary and
inescapable inference, restricts the
court’s jurisdiction in equity, the full
scope of that jurisdiction is to be
recognized and applied.’’ Porter v.
Warner Holding Co., 328 U.S. 395, 398
(1946); Mitchell v. Robert De Mario
Jewelry, Inc., 361 U.S. 288, 291 (1960).
Nothing in the Sherman Act negates this
inherent authority. Section 4 of the
Sherman Act invests district courts with
broad equitable power to ‘‘prevent and
restrain’’ violations of the antitrust laws
and provides that such violations may
be ‘‘enjoined or otherwise prohibited.’’
15 U.S.C. 4. See International Boxing
Club v. United States, 358 U.S. 242, 253
(1959) (relief should ‘‘deprive ‘the
antitrust defendants of the benefits of
their conspiracy,’ ’’ quoting Schine
Chain Theatres v. United States, 334
U.S. 110, 128 (1948)); United States v.
U.S. Steel Corp., 251 U.S. 417, 452
(1920) (Sherman Act’s ‘‘command is
necessarily submissive to the conditions
which may exist and the usual powers
of a court of equity to adapt its remedies
to those conditions’’). The Second
Circuit has held that disgorgement is
among a district court’s inherent
equitable powers, and is a ‘‘wellestablished remedy * * * to prevent
wrongdoers from unjustly enriching
themselves through violations, which
has the effect of deterring subsequent
fraud.’’ SEC v. Cavanagh, 445 F.3d 105,
116–17 (2d Cir. 2006). See also SEC v.
Fischbach, 133 F.3d 170, 175 (2d Cir.
1997); SEC v. Commonwealth Chem.
Secs., Inc., 574 F.2d 90, 102 (2d Cir.
1978) (Friendly, J.).3
3 The
Second Circuit has also permitted
disgorgement under civil RICO, which confers
jurisdiction to ‘‘prevent and restrain violations,’’ 18
U.S.C. 1964(a). See United States v. Carson, 52 F.3d
1173, 1181 (2d Cir. 1995) (‘‘As a general rule,
disgorgement is among the equitable powers
available to the district court by virtue of * * *
§ 1964’’). The DC Circuit, however, has held that
disgorgement categorically is unavailable under
civil RICO. See United States v. Philip Morris, 396
F.3d 1190, 1192, 1202 (DC Cir. 2005) (interlocutory
PO 00000
Frm 00085
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
9951
B. Disgorgement Is Appropriate in This
Case
Disgorgement is necessary to protect
the public interest by depriving
KeySpan of the fruits of its ill-gotten
gains and deterring KeySpan and others
from engaging in similar
anticompetitive conduct in the future.
Absent disgorgement, KeySpan would
be likely to retain all the benefits of its
anticompetitive conduct. A private
lawsuit for damages against KeySpan
would face significant obstacles
imposed by the filed rate doctrine. See
Keogh v. Chicago & N.W. Ry. Co., 260
U.S. 156 (1922). The filed rate doctrine
also makes it unlikely that disgorgement
will lead to duplicative monetary
remedies.
Furthermore, no other remedy would
be as effective to fulfill the remedial
goals of the Sherman Act to ‘‘prevent
and restrain’’ antitrust violations.
Injunctive relief would not be
meaningful, given the facts in this case.
The specific agreement at issue—the
KeySpan Swap—has, by its terms,
expired and the anticompetitive
conduct is unlikely to reoccur as
KeySpan no longer owns the
Ravenswood generation assets.
Disgorgement here will also serve to
restrain KeySpan and others from
participating in similar anticompetitive
conduct. Requiring KeySpan to disgorge
a portion of its ill-gotten gains from its
recent illegal behavior is the only
effective way of achieving relief against
KeySpan, while sending a strong
message to those considering similar
anticompetitive conduct.
IV. Remedies Available to Potential
Private Litigants
Section 4 of the Clayton Act, 15
U.S.C. 15, provides that any person who
has been injured as a result of conduct
prohibited by the antitrust laws may
bring suit in federal court to recover
three times the damages the person has
suffered, as well as costs and reasonable
attorneys’ fees. Entry of the proposed
Final Judgment will neither impair nor
assist the bringing of any private
antitrust damage action. Under the
provisions of Section 5(a) of the Clayton
Act, 15 U.S.C. 16(a), the proposed Final
Judgment has no prima facie effect in
appeal) (Philip Morris I); United States v. Philip
Morris, 566 F.3d 1095, 1108 (DC Cir. 2009) (appeal
after final judgment) (Philip Morris II). The Supreme
Court denied the government’s petition to review
the interlocutory decision in Philip Morris I, 126 S.
Ct. 478 (2005), but on February 19, 2010, the United
States asked the Supreme Court to review Philip
Morris II. In United States v. Loew’s, Inc., 189 F.
Supp. 373 (S.D.N.Y. 1960), this Court declined to
order defendants to renegotiate contracts with third
parties, or to refund money to third parties under
those renegotiated contracts. Id. at 398–99 & n.13.
E:\FR\FM\04MRN1.SGM
04MRN1
9952
Federal Register / Vol. 75, No. 42 / Thursday, March 4, 2010 / Notices
expense, and uncertainty of a full trial
on the merits of the Complaint.
V. Procedures Available for
Modification of the Proposed Final
Judgment
The United States and the defendant
have stipulated that the proposed Final
Judgment may be entered by the Court
after compliance with the provisions of
the APPA, provided that the United
States has not withdrawn its consent.
The APPA conditions entry upon the
Court’s determination that the proposed
Final Judgment is in the public interest.
The APPA provides a period of at
least sixty (60) days preceding the
effective date of the proposed Final
Judgment within which any person may
submit to the United States written
comments regarding the proposed Final
Judgment. Any person who wishes to
comment should do so within sixty (60)
days of the date of publication of this
Competitive Impact Statement in the
Federal Register, or the last date of
publication in a newspaper of the
summary of this Competitive Impact
Statement, whichever is later. All
comments received during this period
will be considered by the United States,
which remains free to withdraw its
consent to the proposed Final Judgment
at any time prior to the Court’s entry of
judgment. The comments and the
response of the United States will be
filed with the Court and published in
the Federal Register.
Written comments should be
submitted to: Donna N. Kooperstein,
Chief, Transportation, Energy &
Agriculture Section, Antitrust Division,
United States Department of Justice, 450
Fifth Street, NW., Suite 8000,
Washington, DC 20530.
The proposed Final Judgment
provides that the Court retains
jurisdiction over this action, and the
parties may apply to the Court for any
order necessary or appropriate for the
modification, interpretation, or
enforcement of the Final Judgment.
mstockstill on DSKH9S0YB1PROD with NOTICES
any subsequent private lawsuit that may
be brought against KeySpan.
VII. Standard of Review Under the
APPA for Proposed Final Judgment
The Clayton Act, as amended by the
APPA, requires that proposed consent
judgments in antitrust cases brought by
the United States be subject to a sixtyday comment period, after which the
court shall determine whether entry of
the proposed Final Judgment ‘‘is in the
public interest.’’ 15 U.S.C. 16(e)(1). In
making that determination, the court, in
accordance with the statute as amended
in 2004, is required to consider:
VI. Alternatives to the Proposed Final
Judgment
The United States considered, as an
alternative to the proposed Final
Judgment, a full trial on the merits
against Defendant. The United States is
satisfied, however, that the
disgorgement of profits is an appropriate
remedy in this matter. A disgorgement
remedy should deter Keyspan and
others from engaging in similar conduct.
Given the facts of this case, the
proposed Final Judgment would protect
competition as effectively as would any
other equitable remedy available
through litigation, but avoids the time,
VerDate Nov<24>2008
16:39 Mar 03, 2010
Jkt 220001
(A) The competitive impact of such
judgment, including termination of alleged
violations, provisions for enforcement and
modification, duration of relief sought,
anticipated effects of alternative remedies
actually considered, whether its terms are
ambiguous, and any other competitive
considerations bearing upon the adequacy of
such judgment that the court deems
necessary to a determination of whether the
consent judgment is in the public interest;
and
(B) The impact of entry of such judgment
upon competition in the relevant market or
markets, upon the public generally and
individuals alleging specific injury from the
violations set forth in the complaint
including consideration of the public benefit,
if any, to be derived from a determination of
the issues at trial.
15 U.S.C. 16(e)(1)(A) & (B). In
considering these statutory factors, the
court’s inquiry is necessarily a limited
one as the United States is entitled to
‘‘broad discretion to settle with the
defendant within the reaches of the
public interest.’’ United States v.
Microsoft Corp., 56 F.3d 1448, 1461 (DC
Cir. 1995); see generally United States v.
SBC Commc’ns, Inc., 489 F. Supp. 2d 1
(D.D.C. 2007) (assessing public interest
standard under the Tunney Act); United
States v. InBev N.V./S.A., 2009–2 Trade
Cas. (CCH) ¶ 76,736, 2009 U.S. Dist.
LEXIS 84787, No. 08–1965 (JR), at *3
(D.D.C. Aug. 11, 2009) (noting that the
court’s review of a consent judgment is
limited and only inquires ‘‘into whether
the government’s determination that the
proposed remedies will cure the
antitrust violations alleged in the
complaint was reasonable, and whether
the mechanism to enforce the final
judgment are clear and manageable’’).4
Under the APPA a court considers,
among other things, the relationship
4 The 2004 amendments substituted ‘‘shall’’ for
‘‘may’’ in directing relevant factors for a court to
consider and amended the list of factors to focus on
competitive considerations and to address
potentially ambiguous judgment terms. Compare 15
U.S.C. 16(e) (2004), with 15 U.S.C. 16(e)(1) (2006);
see also SBC Commc’ns, 489 F. Supp. 2d at 11
(concluding that the 2004 amendments ‘‘effected
minimal changes’’ to Tunney Act review).
PO 00000
Frm 00086
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
between the remedy secured and the
specific allegations set forth in the
United States’ complaint, whether the
decree is sufficiently clear, whether
enforcement mechanisms are sufficient,
and whether the decree may positively
harm third parties. See Microsoft, 56
F.3d at 1458–62. With respect to the
adequacy of the relief secured by the
decree, a court may not ‘‘engage in an
unrestricted evaluation of what relief
would best serve the public.’’ United
States v. BNS, Inc., 858 F.2d 456, 462
(9th Cir. 1988) (citing United States v.
Bechtel Corp., 648 F.2d 660, 666 (9th
Cir. 1981)); see also Microsoft, 56 F.3d
at 1460–62; United States v. Alcoa, Inc.,
152 F. Supp. 2d 37, 40 (D.D.C. 2001);
InBev, 2009 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 84787, at
*3. Courts have held that:
[t]he balancing of competing social and
political interests affected by a proposed
antitrust consent decree must be left, in the
first instance, to the discretion of the
Attorney General. The court’s role in
protecting the public interest is one of
insuring that the government has not
breached its duty to the public in consenting
to the decree. The court is required to
determine not whether a particular decree is
the one that will best serve society, but
whether the settlement is ‘‘within the reaches
of the public interest.’’ More elaborate
requirements might undermine the
effectiveness of antitrust enforcement by
consent decree.
Bechtel, 648 F.2d at 666 (emphasis
added) (citations omitted).5 In
determining whether a proposed
settlement is in the public interest, a
district court ‘‘must accord deference to
the government’s predictions about the
efficacy of its remedies, and may not
require that the remedies perfectly
match the alleged violations.’’ SBC
Commc’ns, 489 F. Supp. 2d at 17; see
also Microsoft, 56 F.3d at 1461 (noting
the need for courts to be ‘‘deferential to
the government’s predictions as to the
effect of the proposed remedies’’);
United States v. Archer-DanielsMidland Co., 272 F. Supp. 2d 1, 6
(D.D.C. 2003) (noting that the court
should grant due respect to the United
States’ prediction as to the effect of
proposed remedies, its perception of the
market structure, and its views of the
nature of the case).
5 Cf. BNS, 858 F.2d at 464 (holding that the
court’s ‘‘ultimate authority under the [APPA] is
limited to approving or disapproving the consent
decree’’); United States v. Gillette Co., 406 F. Supp.
713, 716 (D. Mass. 1975) (noting that, in this way,
the court is constrained to ‘‘look at the overall
picture not hypercritically, nor with a microscope,
but with an artist’s reducing glass’’). See generally
Microsoft, 56 F.3d at 1461 (discussing whether ‘‘the
remedies [obtained in the decree are] so
inconsonant with the allegations charged as to fall
outside of the ‘reaches of the public interest’ ’’).
E:\FR\FM\04MRN1.SGM
04MRN1
mstockstill on DSKH9S0YB1PROD with NOTICES
Federal Register / Vol. 75, No. 42 / Thursday, March 4, 2010 / Notices
Courts have greater flexibility in
approving proposed consent decrees
than in crafting their own decrees
following a finding of liability in a
litigated matter. ‘‘[A] proposed decree
must be approved even if it falls short
of the remedy the court would impose
on its own, as long as it falls within the
range of acceptability or is ‘within the
reaches of public interest.’ ’’ United
States v. Am. Tel. & Tel. Co., 552 F.
Supp. 131, 151 (D.D.C. 1982) (citations
omitted) (quoting United States v.
Gillette Co., 406 F. Supp. 713, 716 (D.
Mass. 1975)), aff’d sub nom. Maryland
v. United States, 460 U.S. 1001 (1983);
see also United States v. Alcan
Aluminum Ltd., 605 F. Supp. 619, 622
(W.D. Ky. 1985) (approving the consent
decree even though the court would
have imposed a greater remedy). To
meet this standard, the United States
‘‘need only provide a factual basis for
concluding that the settlements are
reasonably adequate remedies for the
alleged harms.’’ SBC Commc’ns, 489 F.
Supp. 2d at 17.
Moreover, the court’s role under the
APPA is limited to reviewing the
remedy in relationship to the violations
that the United States has alleged in its
Complaint, and does not authorize the
court to ‘‘construct [its] own
hypothetical case and then evaluate the
decree against that case.’’ Microsoft, 56
F.3d at 1459; see also InBev, 2009 U.S.
Dist. LEXIS 84787, at *20 (‘‘[T]he ‘public
interest’ is not to be measured by
comparing the violations alleged in the
complaint against those the court
believes could have, or even should
have, been alleged.’’). Because the
‘‘court’s authority to review the decree
depends entirely on the government’s
exercising its prosecutorial discretion by
bringing a case in the first place,’’ it
follows that ‘‘the court is only
authorized to review the decree itself,’’
and not to ‘‘effectively redraft the
complaint’’ to inquire into other matters
that the United States did not pursue.
Microsoft, 56 F.3d. at 1459–60. Courts
‘‘cannot look beyond the complaint in
making the public interest
determination unless the complaint is
drafted so narrowly as to make a
mockery of judicial power.’’ SBC
Commc’ns, 489 F. Supp. 2d at 15.
In its 2004 amendments, Congress
made clear its intent to preserve the
practical benefits of utilizing consent
decrees in antitrust enforcement, adding
the unambiguous instruction that
‘‘[n]othing in this section shall be
construed to require the court to
conduct an evidentiary hearing or to
require the court to permit anyone to
intervene.’’ 15 U.S.C. 16(e)(2). This
language effectuates what Congress
VerDate Nov<24>2008
16:39 Mar 03, 2010
Jkt 220001
intended when it enacted the Tunney
Act in 1974, as Senator Tunney
explained: ‘‘[t]he court is nowhere
compelled to go to trial or to engage in
extended proceedings which might have
the effect of vitiating the benefits of
prompt and less costly settlement
through the consent decree process.’’
119 Cong. Rec. 24,598 (1973) (statement
of Senator Tunney). Rather, the
procedure for the public interest
determination is left to the discretion of
the court, with the recognition that the
court’s ‘‘scope of review remains sharply
proscribed by precedent and the nature
of Tunney Act proceedings.’’ SBC
Commc’ns, 489 F. Supp. 2d at 11.6
VIII. Determinative Documents
There are no determinative materials
or documents within the meaning of the
APPA that the United States considered
in formulating the proposed Final
Judgment.
Dated: February 22, 2010.
Respectfully submitted,
For Plaintiff The United States of America
David E. Altschuler,
Jade Alice Eaton,
Trial Attorneys, United States Department of
Justice, Antitrust Division, Transportation,
Energy & Agriculture Section, 450 5th Street,
NW., Suite 8000, Washington, DC 20530,
Telephone: (202) 307–6316,
david.altschuler@usdoj.gov,
jade.eaton@usdoj.gov.
[FR Doc. 2010–4545 Filed 3–3–10; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 4410–11–P
6 See United States v. Enova Corp., 107 F. Supp.
2d 10, 17 (D.D.C. 2000) (noting that the ‘‘Tunney
Act expressly allows the court to make its public
interest determination on the basis of the
competitive impact statement and response to
comments alone’’); United States v. Mid-Am.
Dairymen, Inc., 1977–1 Trade Cas. (CCH) ¶ 61,508,
at 71,980 (W.D. Mo. 1977) (‘‘Absent a showing of
corrupt failure of the government to discharge its
duty, the Court, in making its public interest
finding, should * * * carefully consider the
explanations of the government in the competitive
impact statement and its responses to comments in
order to determine whether those explanations are
reasonable under the circumstances.’’); S. Rep. No.
93–298, 93d Cong., 1st Sess., at 6 (1973) (‘‘Where
the public interest can be meaningfully evaluated
simply on the basis of briefs and oral arguments,
that is the approach that should be utilized.’’).
PO 00000
Frm 00087
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
9953
DEPARTMENT OF LABOR
Occupational Safety and Health
Administration
[Docket No. OSHA–2010–0007]
Definition and Requirements for a
Nationally Recognized Testing
Laboratory (NRTL); Extension of the
Office of Management and Budget’s
(OMB) Approval of Information
Collection (Paperwork) Requirements
AGENCY: Occupational Safety and Health
Administration (OSHA), Labor.
ACTION: Request for comment.
SUMMARY: OSHA requests comment
concerning its proposed extension of the
information collection requirements
specified by its Regulation on the
Definition and Requirements for a
Nationally Recognized Testing
Laboratory (29 CFR 1910.7). The
Regulation specifies procedures that
organizations must follow to apply for,
and to maintain, OSHA’s recognition to
test and certify equipment, products, or
material.
DATES: Comments must be submitted
(postmarked, sent, or received) by
May 3, 2010.
ADDRESSES: Electronically: You may
submit comments and attachments
electronically at https://
www.regulations.gov, which is the
Federal eRulemaking Portal. Follow the
instructions online for submitting
comments.
Facsimile: If your comments,
including attachments, are not longer
than 10 pages, you may fax them to the
OSHA Docket Office at (202) 693–1648.
Mail, hand delivery, express mail,
messenger, or courier service: When
using this method, you must submit
three copies of your comments and
attachments to the OSHA Docket Office,
Docket No. OSHA–2010–0007, U.S.
Department of Labor, Occupational
Safety and Health Administration,
Room N–2625, 200 Constitution
Avenue, NW., Washington, DC 20210.
Deliveries (hand, express mail,
messenger, and courier service) are
accepted during the Department of
Labor’s and Docket Office’s normal
business hours, 8:15 a.m. to 4:45 p.m.,
e.t.
Instructions: All submissions must
include the Agency name and OSHA
docket number for the Information
Collection Request (ICR) (OSHA–2010–
0007). All comments, including any
personal information you provide, are
placed in the public docket without
change, and may be made available
online at https://www.regulations.gov.
E:\FR\FM\04MRN1.SGM
04MRN1
Agencies
[Federal Register Volume 75, Number 42 (Thursday, March 4, 2010)]
[Notices]
[Pages 9946-9953]
From the Federal Register Online via the Government Printing Office [www.gpo.gov]
[FR Doc No: 2010-4545]
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE
Antitrust Division
United States v. Keyspan Corporation; Proposed Final Judgment and
Competitive Impact Statement
Notice is hereby given pursuant to the Antitrust Procedures and
Penalties Act, 15 U.S.C. 16(b)-(h), that a proposed Final Judgment,
Stipulation and Competitive Impact Statement have been filed with the
United States District Court for the Southern District of New York in
United States of America v. KeySpan Corp., Civil Case No. 10-CIV-1415.
On February 22, 2010, the United States filed a Complaint alleging that
KeySpan Corporation (``KeySpan'') entered into an agreement with a
financial services company, the likely effect of which was to increase
prices in the New York City (NYISO Zone J) Capacity Market, in
violation of Section 1 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. 1. The proposed
Final Judgment, filed the same time as the Complaint, requires KeySpan
to pay the government $12 million dollars.
Copies of the Complaint, proposed Final Judgment and Competitive
Impact Statement are available for inspection at the Department of
Justice, Antitrust Division, Antitrust Documents Group, 450 Fifth
Street, NW., Suite 1010, Washington, DC 20530 (telephone: 202-514-
2481), on the Department of Justice's Web site at https://www.justice.gov/atr, and at the Office of the Clerk of the United
States District Court for the Southern District of New York. Copies of
these materials may be obtained from the Antitrust Division upon
request and payment of the copying fee set by Department of Justice
regulations.
Public comment is invited within 60 days of the date of this
notice. Such comments, and responses thereto, will be published in the
Federal Register and filed with the Court. Comments should be directed
to Donna N. Kooperstein, Chief, Transportation, Energy, and Agriculture
Section, Antitrust Division, U.S. Department of Justice, 450 Fifth
Street, NW., Suite 8000, Washington, DC 20530 (telephone: 202-307-
6349).
Patricia A. Brink,
Deputy Director of Operations and Civil Enforcement.
United States District Court for the Southern District of New York
Civil Action No.: 10-cv-1415 (WHP)
ECF CASE
United States of America, U.S. Department of Justice, Antitrust
Division, 450 5th Street, NW., Suite 8000, Washington, DC 20530,
Plaintiff, v. Keyspan Corporation, 1 Metrotech Center, Brooklyn, NY
11201, Defendant.
Received: February 22, 2010
Complaint
The United States of America, acting under the direction of the
Attorney General of the United States, brings this civil antitrust
action under Section 4 of the Sherman Act, as amended, 15 U.S.C.
[[Page 9947]]
4, to obtain equitable and other relief from defendant's violation of
Section 1 of the Sherman Act, as amended, 15 U.S.C. 1.
On January 18, 2006, KeySpan Corporation (``KeySpan'') and a
financial services company executed an agreement (the ``Keyspan Swap'')
that ensured that KeySpan would withhold substantial output from the
New York City electricity generating capacity market, a market that was
created to ensure the supply of sufficient generation capacity for New
York City consumers of electricity. The likely effect of the Keyspan
Swap was to increase capacity prices for the retail electricity
suppliers who must purchase capacity, and, in turn, to increase the
prices consumers pay for electricity.
I. Introduction
1. Between 2003 and 2006, KeySpan, the largest seller of
electricity generating capacity (``installed capacity'') in the New
York City market, earned substantial revenues due to tight supply
conditions. Because purchasers of capacity required almost all of
KeySpan's output to meet expected demand, KeySpan's ability to set
price levels was limited only by a regulatory ceiling (called a ``bid
cap''). Indeed, the market price for capacity was consistently at or
near KeySpan's bid cap, with KeySpan sacrificing sales on only a small
fraction of its capacity.
2. But market conditions were about to change. Two large, new
electricity generation plants were slated to come on line in 2006 (with
no exit expected until at least 2009), breaking the capacity shortage
that had kept prices at the capped levels.
3. KeySpan could prevent the new capacity from lowering prices by
withholding a substantial amount of its own capacity from the market.
This ``bid the cap'' strategy would keep market prices high, but at a
significant cost--the sacrificed sales would reduce KeySpan's revenues
by as much as $90 million a year. Alternatively, KeySpan could compete
with its rivals for sales by bidding more capacity at lower prices.
This ``competitive strategy'' could earn KeySpan more than bidding its
cap, but it carried a risk--KeySpan's competitors could undercut its
price and take sales away, making the strategy less profitable than
``bidding the cap.''
4. KeySpan searched for a way to avoid both the revenue decline
from bidding its cap and the revenue risks of competitive bidding. It
decided to enter an agreement that gave it a financial interest in the
capacity of Astoria--KeySpan's largest competitor. By providing KeySpan
revenues on a larger base of sales, such an agreement would make a
``bid the cap'' strategy more profitable than a successful competitive
bid strategy. Rather than directly approach its competitor, KeySpan
turned to a financial services company to act as the counterparty to
the agreement--the KeySpan Swap--recognizing that the financial
services company would, and in fact did, enter an offsetting agreement
with Astoria (the ``Astoria Hedge'').
5. With KeySpan deriving revenues from both its own and Astoria's
capacity, the KeySpan Swap removed any incentive for KeySpan to bid
competitively, locking it into bidding its cap. Capacity prices
remained as high as if no entry had occurred.
II. Defendant
6. KeySpan Corporation is a New York corporation with its principal
place of business in New York City. During the relevant period of the
allegations in this Complaint, KeySpan owned approximately 2,400
megawatts of electricity generating capacity at its Ravenswood
electrical generation facility, which is located in New York City.
KeySpan had revenues of approximately $850 million in 2006 and $700
million in 2007 from the sale of energy and capacity at its Ravenswood
facility.
III. Jurisdiction and Venue
7. The United States files this complaint under Section 4 of the
Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. 4, seeking equitable relief from defendant's
violation of Section 1 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. 1.
8. This court has jurisdiction over this matter pursuant to 15
U.S.C. 4 and 28 U.S.C. 1331 and 1337.
9. Defendant waives any objection to venue and personal
jurisdiction in this judicial district for the purpose of this
Complaint.
10. Defendant engaged in interstate commerce during the relevant
period of the allegations in this Complaint; KeySpan's electric
generating units interconnected with generating units across the
country, and KeySpan regularly sold electricity to customers outside
New York.
11. One generation facility located in New Jersey supplies capacity
to the New York City installed capacity market.
IV. The New York City Installed Capacity Market
12. Sellers of retail electricity must purchase a product from
generators known as ``installed capacity.'' Installed capacity is a
product created by the New York Independent System Operator (``NYISO'')
to ensure that sufficient generation capacity exists to meet expected
electricity needs. Companies selling electricity to consumers in New
York City are required to make installed capacity payments that relate
to their expected peak demand plus a share of reserve capacity (to
cover extra facilities needed in case a generating facility breaks
down). These payments assure that retail electric companies do not sell
more electricity than the system can deliver and also encourage
electric generating companies to build new facilities as needed.
13. The price for installed capacity has been set through auctions
administered by the NYISO. The rules under which these auctions are
conducted have changed from time to time. Unless otherwise noted, the
description of the installed capacity market in the following
paragraphs relates to the period May 2003 through March 2008.
14. Because transmission constraints limit the amount of energy
that can be imported into the New York City area from the power grid,
the NYISO requires retail providers of electricity to customers in New
York City to purchase 80% of their capacity from generators in that
region. The NYISO operates separate capacity auctions for the New York
City region (also known as ``In-City'' and ``Zone J''). The NYISO
organizes the auctions to serve two distinct seasonal periods, summer
(May through October) and winter (November through April). For each
season, the NYISO conducts seasonal, monthly and spot auctions in which
capacity can be acquired for all or some of the seasonal period.
15. In each of the types of auctions, capacity suppliers offer
price and quantity bids. Supplier bids are ``stacked'' from lowest-
priced to highest, and compared to the total amount of demand being
satisfied in the auction. The offering price of the last bid in the
``stack'' needed to meet requisite demand establishes the market price
for all capacity bid into that auction. Capacity bid at higher than
this price is unsold, as is any excess capacity bid at what becomes the
market price.
16. The New York City Installed Capacity (``NYC Capacity'') Market
constitutes a relevant geographic and product market.
17. The NYC Capacity Market is highly concentrated, with three
firms--KeySpan, NRG Energy, Inc. (``NRG'') and Astoria Generating
Company (a joint venture of Madison Dearborn Partners, LLC and US Power
Generating Company, which purchased the Astoria generating assets from
Reliant Energy,
[[Page 9948]]
Inc. in February 2006)--controlling a substantial portion of generating
capacity in the market. Because purchasers of capacity require at least
some of each of these three suppliers' output to meet expected demand,
the firms are subject to a bid and price cap for nearly all of their
generating capacity in New York City and are not allowed to sell that
capacity outside of the NYISO auction process. The NYISO-set bid cap
for KeySpan is the highest of the three firms, followed by NRG and
Astoria.
18. KeySpan possessed market power in the NYC Capacity Market.
19. It is difficult and time-consuming to build or expand
generating facilities within the NYC Capacity Market given limited
undeveloped space for building or expanding generating facilities and
extensive regulatory obligations.
V. Keyspan's Plan To Avoid Competition
20. From June 2003 through December 2005, KeySpan set the market
price in the New York City spot auction by bidding its capacity at its
cap. Given extremely tight supply and demand conditions, KeySpan needed
to withhold only a small amount of capacity to ensure that the market
cleared at its cap.
21. KeySpan anticipated that the tight supply and demand conditions
in the NYC Capacity Market would change in 2006, due to the entry of
approximately 1000 MW of new generation. Because of the addition of
this new capacity, KeySpan would have to withhold significantly more
capacity from the market and would earn substantially lower revenues if
it continued to bid all of its capacity at its bid cap. KeySpan
anticipated that demand growth and retirement of old generation units
would restore tight supply and demand conditions in 2009.
22. KeySpan could no longer be confident that ``bidding the cap''
would remain its best strategy during the 2006-2009 period. It
considered various competitive bidding strategies under which KeySpan
would compete with its rivals for sales by bidding more capacity at
lower prices. These strategies could potentially produce much higher
returns for KeySpan but carried the risk that competitors would
undercut its price and take sales away, making the strategy less
profitable than ``bidding the cap.''
23. KeySpan also considered acquiring Astoria's generating assets,
which were for sale. This would have solved the problem that new entry
posed for KeySpan's revenue stream, as Astoria's capacity would have
provided KeySpan with sufficient additional revenues to make continuing
to ``bid the cap'' its best strategy. KeySpan consulted with a
financial services company about acquiring the assets. But KeySpan soon
concluded that its acquisition of its largest competitor would raise
serious market power issues.
24. Instead of purchasing the Astoria assets, KeySpan decided to
acquire a financial interest in substantially all of Astoria's
capacity. KeySpan would pay Astoria's owner a fixed revenue stream in
return for the revenues generated from Astoria's capacity sales in the
auctions.
25. KeySpan did not approach Astoria directly and instead sought a
counterparty to enter into a financial agreement providing KeySpan with
payments derived from the market clearing price for an amount of
capacity essentially equivalent to what Astoria owned. KeySpan
recognized the counterparty would need simultaneously to enter into an
agreement with another capacity supplier that would offset the
counterparty's payments to KeySpan, and KeySpan knew that Astoria was
the only supplier with sufficient capacity to do so. KeySpan turned to
the same financial services company that it had consulted about the
potential acquisition of Astoria's assets. The financial services
company agreed to serve as the counterparty but, as expected, informed
KeySpan that the agreement was contingent on the financial services
company also entering into an offsetting agreement with the owner of
the Astoria generating assets.
VI. The Agreements
26. On or about January 9, 2006, KeySpan and the financial services
company finalized the terms of the KeySpan Swap. Under the agreement,
if the market price for capacity was above $7.57 per kW-month, the
financial services company would pay KeySpan the difference between the
market price and $7.57 times 1800 MW; if the market price was below
$7.57, KeySpan would pay the financial services company the difference
times 1800 MW.
27. The KeySpan Swap was executed on January 18, 2006. The term of
the KeySpan Swap ran from May 2006 through April 2009.
28. On or about January 9, 2006, the financial services company and
Astoria finalized the terms of the Astoria Hedge. Under that agreement,
if the market price for capacity was above $7.07 per kW-month, Astoria
would pay the financial services company the difference times 1800 MW;
if the market price was below $7.07, Astoria would be paid the
difference times 1800 MW.
29. The Astoria Hedge was executed on January 11, 2006. The term of
the Astoria Hedge ran from May 2006 through April 2009, matching the
duration of the KeySpan Swap.
VII. The Competitive Effect of the Keyspan Swap
30. The clear tendency of the KeySpan Swap was to alter KeySpan's
bidding in the NYC Capacity Market auctions.
31. Without the Swap, KeySpan likely would have chosen from a range
of potentially profitable competitive strategies in response to the
entry of new capacity. Had it done so, the price of capacity would have
declined. By transferring a financial interest in Astoria's capacity to
KeySpan, however, the Swap effectively eliminated KeySpan's incentive
to compete for sales in the same way a purchase of Astoria or a direct
agreement between KeySpan and Astoria would have done. By providing
KeySpan revenues from Astoria's capacity, in addition to Keyspan's own
revenues, the Swap made bidding the cap KeySpan's most profitable
strategy regardless of its rivals' bids.
32. After the KeySpan Swap went into effect in May 2006, KeySpan
consistently bid its capacity at its cap even though a significant
portion of its capacity went unsold. Despite the addition of
significant new generating capacity in New York City, the market price
of capacity did not decline.
33. In August 2007, the State of New York conditioned the sale of
KeySpan to a new owner on the divestiture of KeySpan's Ravenswood
generating assets and required KeySpan to bid its New York City
capacity at zero from March 2008 until the divestiture was completed.
Since March 2008, the market price for capacity has declined.
34. But for the KeySpan Swap, installed capacity likely would have
been procured at a lower price in New York City from May 2006 through
February 2008.
35. The KeySpan Swap produced no countervailing efficiencies.
VIII. Violation Alleged
36. Plaintiff incorporates the allegations of paragraphs 1 through
35 above.
37. KeySpan entered into an agreement the likely effect of which
has been to increase prices in the NYC Capacity Market, in violation of
Section 1 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. 1.
[[Page 9949]]
IX. Prayer for Relief
Wherefore, Plaintiff prays:
1. That the Court adjudge and decree that the KeySpan Swap
agreement constitutes an illegal restraint in the sale of installed
capacity in the New York City market in violation of Section 1 of the
Sherman Act;
2. That plaintiff shall have such other relief, including equitable
monetary relief, as the nature of this case may require and as is just
and proper to prevent the recurrence of the alleged violation and to
dissipate the anticompetitive effects of the violation; and
3. That plaintiff recover the costs of this action.
Dated this 22nd day of February 2010.
Respectfully Submitted,
Christine A. Varney,
Assistant Attorney General.
Molly S. Boast,
Deputy Assistant Attorney General.
William F. Cavanaugh, Jr.,
Deputy Assistant Attorney General.
Donna N. Kooperstein,
Chief.
William H. Stalling,
Assistant Chief.
Transportation, Energy & Agriculture Section Suite 8000.
Patricia A. Brink,
Deputy Director of Operations.
Jade Alice Eaton,
J. Richard Doidge,
John W. Elias,
Trial Attorneys.
U.S. Department of Justice, Antitrust Division, Transportation,
Energy & Agriculture Section, 450 5th Street, NW., Suite 8000,
Washington, DC 20530, Telephone: (202) 353-1560, Facismilie (202)
616-2441, jade.eaton@usdoj.gov.
United States District Court for the Southern District of New York
ECF Case
Civil Action No. 10-cv-1415 (WHP)
United States of America, Plaintiff, v. Keyspan Corporation,
Defendant.
Received: February 22, 2010
Final Judgment
Whereas plaintiff United States of America filed its Complaint
alleging that Defendant KeySpan Corporation (``KeySpan'') violated
Section 1 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. 1, and plaintiff and KeySpan,
through their respective attorneys, having consented to the entry of
this Final Judgment without trial or adjudication of any issue of fact
or law, for settlement purposes only, and without this Final Judgment
constituting any evidence against or an admission by KeySpan with
respect to any allegation contained in the Complaint:
Now, therefore, before the taking of any testimony and without
trial or adjudication of any issue of fact or law herein, and upon the
consent of the parties hereto, it is hereby ordered, adjudged, and
decreed:
1. Jurisdiction
This Court has jurisdiction of the subject matter herein and of
each of the parties consenting hereto. The Complaint states a claim
upon which relief may be granted against KeySpan under Sections 1 and 4
of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. 1 and 4.
2. Applicability
This Final Judgment applies to KeySpan and each of its successors,
assigns, and to all other persons in active concert or participation
with it who shall have received actual notice of the Settlement
Agreement and Order by personal service or otherwise.
3. Relief
A. Within thirty (30) days of the entry of this Final Judgment,
KeySpan shall pay to the United States the sum of twelve million
dollars ($12,000,000.00).
B. The payment specified above shall be made by wire transfer.
Before making the transfer, KeySpan shall contact Janie Ingalls, of the
Antitrust Division's Antitrust Documents Group, at (202) 514-2481 for
wire transfer instructions.
C. In the event of a default in payment, interest at the rate of
eighteen (18) percent per annum shall accrue thereon from the date of
default to the date of payment.
4. Retention of Jurisdiction
This Court retains jurisdiction to enable any party to this Final
Judgment to apply to this Court at any time for further orders and
directions as may be necessary or appropriate to carry out or construe
this Final Judgment, to modify any of its provisions, to enforce
compliance, and to punish violations of its provisions.
5. Public Interest Determination
Entry of this Final Judgment is in the public interest. The parties
have complied with the requirements of the Antitrust Procedures and
Penalties Act, 15 U.S.C. 16, including making copies available to the
public of this Final Judgment, the Competitive Impact Statement, and
any comments thereon and plaintiff's responses to comments. Based upon
the record before the Court, which includes the Competitive Impact
Statement and any comments and response to comments filed with the
Court, entry of this Final Judgment is in the public interest.
Dated:
United States District Judge.
United States District Court for the Southern District of New York
ECF Case
Civil Action No. 10-cv-1415 (WHP)
United States of America, Plaintiff, v. Keyspan Corporation,
Defendant.
Filed 02/23/2010
Competitive Impact Statement
Plaintiff United States of America (``United States''), pursuant to
Section 2(b) of the Antitrust Procedures and Penalties Act (``APPA'' or
``Tunney Act''), 15 U.S.C. 16(b)-(h), files this Competitive Impact
Statement relating to the proposed Final Judgment submitted for entry
in this civil antitrust proceeding.
I. Nature and Purpose of the Proceedings
The United States brought this lawsuit against Defendant KeySpan
Corporation (``KeySpan'') on February 22, 2010, to remedy a violation
of Section 1 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. 1. On January 18, 2006,
KeySpan entered into an agreement in the form of a financial derivative
(the ``KeySpan Swap'') essentially transferring to KeySpan, the largest
supplier of electricity generating capacity in the New York City
market, the capacity of its largest competitor. The KeySpan Swap
ensured that KeySpan would withhold substantial output from the
capacity market, a market that was created to ensure the supply of
sufficient generation capacity for the millions of New York City
consumers of electricity. The likely effect of this agreement was to
increase capacity prices for the retail electricity suppliers who must
purchase capacity, and, in turn, to increase the prices consumers pay
for electricity.
The proposed Final Judgment remedies this violation by requiring
KeySpan to disgorge profits obtained through the anticompetitive
agreement. Under the terms of the proposed Final Judgment, KeySpan will
surrender $12 million to the Treasury of the United States.
Disgorgement will deter KeySpan and others from future violations of
the antitrust laws.
The United States and KeySpan have stipulated that the proposed
Final Judgment may be entered after compliance with the APPA, unless
the United States withdraws its consent. Entry of the proposed Final
Judgment would terminate this action, except that this Court would
retain jurisdiction to construe, modify, and enforce the
[[Page 9950]]
proposed Final Judgment and to punish violations thereof.
II. Description of the Events Giving Rise to the Alleged Violation of
the Antitrust Laws
A. The Defendant
KeySpan Corporation is a New York corporation with its principal
place of business in New York City. During the relevant period of the
allegations in this Complaint, KeySpan owned approximately 2400
megawatts of electricity generating capacity at its Ravenswood
electrical generation facility, which is located in New York City.
KeySpan had revenues of approximately $850 million in 2006 and $700
million in 2007 from the sale of energy and capacity at its Ravenswood
facility.
B. The Market
In the state of New York, sellers of retail electricity must
purchase a product from generators known as installed capacity
(``capacity'').\1\ Electricity retailers are required to purchase
capacity in an amount equal to their expected peak energy demand plus a
share of reserve capacity. These payments assure that retail electric
companies do not use more electricity than the system can deliver and
encourage electric generating companies to build new facilities as
needed. Because transmission constraints limit the amount of energy
that can be imported into the New York City area from the power grid,
the New York Independent System Operator (``NYISO'') requires retail
providers of electricity to customers in New York City to purchase 80%
of their capacity from generators in that region. Thus, the New York
City Installed Capacity (``NYC Capacity'') Market constitutes a
relevant geographic and product market.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1\ Except where noted otherwise, this description pertains to
the market conditions that existed from May 2003 through March 2008.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The price for installed capacity has been set through auctions
administered by the NYISO. The NYISO organizes the auctions to serve
two distinct seasonal periods, summer (May though October) and winter
(November through April). For each season, the NYISO conducts seasonal,
monthly, and spot auctions in which capacity can be acquired for all or
some of the seasonal period. Capacity suppliers offer price and
quantity bids in each of these three auctions. Supplier bids are
``stacked'' from lowest-priced to highest. The stack is then compared
to the amount of demand. The offering price of the last bid in the
``stack'' needed to meet requisite demand establishes the market price
for all capacity sold into that auction. Any capacity bid at higher
than this price is unsold, as is any excess capacity bid at what
becomes the market price.
The NYC Capacity Market was highly concentrated during the relevant
period, with three firms--Astoria, NRG Energy, Inc., and KeySpan--
controlling a substantial portion of the market's generating capacity.
These three were designated as pivotal suppliers by the Federal Energy
Regulatory Commission, meaning that at least some of each of these
three suppliers' output was required to satisfy demand. The three firms
were subject to bid and price caps--KeySpan's being the highest--for
nearly all of their generating capacity in New York City and were not
allowed to sell their capacity outside of the NYISO auction process.
C. The Alleged Violation
1. KeySpan Assesses Plans for Changed Market Conditions
From June 2003 through December 2005, almost all installed capacity
in the market was needed to meet demand. With these tight market
conditions, KeySpan could sell almost all of its capacity into the
market, even while bidding at its cap. KeySpan did so, and the market
cleared at the price established by the cap, with only a small fraction
of KeySpan's capacity remaining unsold.
KeySpan anticipated that the tight supply and demand conditions in
the NYC Capacity Market would end in 2006 due to the entry into the
market of approximately 1000 MW of generation capacity, and would not
return until 2009 with the retirement of old generation units and
demand growth.
KeySpan could no longer be confident that ``bid the cap'' would
remain its best strategy during the 2006-2009 period. The ``bid the
cap'' strategy would keep market prices high, but at a significant
cost. KeySpan would have to withhold a significant additional amount of
capacity to account for the new entry. The additional withholding would
reduce KeySpan's revenues by as much as $90 million a year.
Alternatively, KeySpan could compete with its rivals for sales by
bidding more capacity at lower prices. KeySpan considered various
competitive bidding strategies. These could potentially produce much
higher returns for KeySpan than bidding the cap but carried the risk
that competitors would undercut its price and take sales away, making
the strategy potentially less profitable than bidding the cap.
KeySpan also considered acquiring Astoria's generating assets,
which were for sale. This would have solved the problem that new entry
posed for KeySpan's revenue stream, as Astoria's capacity would have
provided KeySpan with sufficient additional revenues to make continuing
to bid its cap its best strategy. KeySpan consulted with a financial
services company about acquiring the assets, but soon concluded that
its acquisition of its largest competitor would raise market power
issues.
2. KeySpan Pursues an Anticompetitive and Unlawful Agreement
Instead of purchasing the Astoria assets, KeySpan decided to
acquire a financial interest in Astoria's capacity. KeySpan would pay
Astoria's owner a fixed revenue stream in return for the revenues
generated from Astoria's capacity sales in the auctions. The
competitive effect of doing so would be similar to that of actually
purchasing Astoria's capacity.
KeySpan did not approach Astoria directly and instead sought a
counterparty to enter into a financial agreement providing KeySpan with
payments derived from the market clearing price for an amount of
capacity essentially equivalent to what Astoria owned. KeySpan
recognized the counterparty would need simultaneously to enter into an
agreement with another capacity supplier that would offset the
counterparty's payments to Keyspan, and KeySpan knew that Astoria was
the only supplier with sufficient capacity to do so. KeySpan turned to
the same financial services company that it had consulted about the
potential acquisition of Astoria's assets. The financial services
company agreed to serve as the counterparty, but, as expected, informed
KeySpan that the agreement was contingent on the financial services
company also entering into an offsetting agreement with the owner of
the Astoria generating assets (the ``Astoria Hedge'').
On or about January 9, 2006, KeySpan and the financial services
company finalized the terms of the KeySpan Swap. Under the agreement,
if the market price for capacity was above $7.57 per kW-month, the
financial services company would pay KeySpan the difference between the
market price and $7.57 times 1800 MW; if the market price was below
$7.57, KeySpan would pay the financial services company the difference
times 1800 MW. The KeySpan Swap was executed on January 18, 2006. The
term of the KeySpan
[[Page 9951]]
Swap ran from May 2006 through April 2009.
On or about January 9, 2006, the financial services company and
Astoria finalized terms to the Astoria Hedge. Under that agreement, if
the market price for capacity was above $7.07 per kW-month, Astoria
would pay the financial services company the difference times 1800 MW;
if the market price was below $7.07, Astoria would be paid the
difference times 1800 MW. The Astoria Hedge was executed on January 11,
2006. The term of the Astoria Hedge ran from May 2006 through April
2009, matching the duration of the KeySpan Swap.
3. The Effect of the KeySpan Swap
The clear tendency of the KeySpan Swap was to alter KeySpan's
bidding in the NYC Capacity Market auctions.
Without the swap, KeySpan likely would have chosen from a range of
potentially profitable competitive strategies in response to the entry
of new capacity and, had it done so, the price of capacity would have
declined. The swap, however, effectively eliminated KeySpan's incentive
to compete for sales. By adding revenues from Astoria's capacity to
KeySpan's own, the KeySpan Swap made bidding the cap KeySpan's most
profitable strategy regardless of its rivals' bids.
After the KeySpan Swap went into effect in May 2006, KeySpan
consistently bid its capacity into the capacity auctions at its cap
even though a significant portion of its capacity went unsold. Despite
the addition of significant new generating capacity in New York City,
the market price of capacity did not decline.
By transferring a financial interest in Astoria's capacity to
KeySpan, the Swap effectively eliminated KeySpan's incentive to compete
for sales in the same way a purchase of Astoria or a direct agreement
between KeySpan and Astoria would have done. But for the Swap,
installed capacity likely would have been procured at a lower price in
New York City from May 2006 through February 2008.\2\ The Swap produced
no countervailing efficiencies.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\2\ The effects of the swap continued until March 2008, at which
time changes in regulatory conditions eliminated KeySpan's ability
to affect the market price. KeySpan was sold to another company in
August 2007. The State of New York conditioned its approval of the
acquisition on the divestiture of KeySpan's Ravenswood generating
assets and required KeySpan to bid its New York City capacity at
zero from March 2008 until the divestiture was completed. Since
then, the market price for capacity has declined.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
III. Explanation of the Proposed Final Judgment
The proposed Final Judgment requires KeySpan to disgorge profits
gained as a result of its unlawful agreement restraining trade. KeySpan
is to surrender $12 million to the Treasury of the United States.
A. Disgorgement Is Available Under the Sherman Act
Although the Antitrust Division has not previously sought
disgorgement as a remedy under the Sherman Act, district courts have
the authority to order such equitable relief. The Supreme Court has
held that ``[u]nless a statute in so many words, or by a necessary and
inescapable inference, restricts the court's jurisdiction in equity,
the full scope of that jurisdiction is to be recognized and applied.''
Porter v. Warner Holding Co., 328 U.S. 395, 398 (1946); Mitchell v.
Robert De Mario Jewelry, Inc., 361 U.S. 288, 291 (1960). Nothing in the
Sherman Act negates this inherent authority. Section 4 of the Sherman
Act invests district courts with broad equitable power to ``prevent and
restrain'' violations of the antitrust laws and provides that such
violations may be ``enjoined or otherwise prohibited.'' 15 U.S.C. 4.
See International Boxing Club v. United States, 358 U.S. 242, 253
(1959) (relief should ``deprive `the antitrust defendants of the
benefits of their conspiracy,' '' quoting Schine Chain Theatres v.
United States, 334 U.S. 110, 128 (1948)); United States v. U.S. Steel
Corp., 251 U.S. 417, 452 (1920) (Sherman Act's ``command is necessarily
submissive to the conditions which may exist and the usual powers of a
court of equity to adapt its remedies to those conditions''). The
Second Circuit has held that disgorgement is among a district court's
inherent equitable powers, and is a ``well-established remedy * * * to
prevent wrongdoers from unjustly enriching themselves through
violations, which has the effect of deterring subsequent fraud.'' SEC
v. Cavanagh, 445 F.3d 105, 116-17 (2d Cir. 2006). See also SEC v.
Fischbach, 133 F.3d 170, 175 (2d Cir. 1997); SEC v. Commonwealth Chem.
Secs., Inc., 574 F.2d 90, 102 (2d Cir. 1978) (Friendly, J.).\3\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\3\ The Second Circuit has also permitted disgorgement under
civil RICO, which confers jurisdiction to ``prevent and restrain
violations,'' 18 U.S.C. 1964(a). See United States v. Carson, 52
F.3d 1173, 1181 (2d Cir. 1995) (``As a general rule, disgorgement is
among the equitable powers available to the district court by virtue
of * * * Sec. 1964''). The DC Circuit, however, has held that
disgorgement categorically is unavailable under civil RICO. See
United States v. Philip Morris, 396 F.3d 1190, 1192, 1202 (DC Cir.
2005) (interlocutory appeal) (Philip Morris I); United States v.
Philip Morris, 566 F.3d 1095, 1108 (DC Cir. 2009) (appeal after
final judgment) (Philip Morris II). The Supreme Court denied the
government's petition to review the interlocutory decision in Philip
Morris I, 126 S. Ct. 478 (2005), but on February 19, 2010, the
United States asked the Supreme Court to review Philip Morris II. In
United States v. Loew's, Inc., 189 F. Supp. 373 (S.D.N.Y. 1960),
this Court declined to order defendants to renegotiate contracts
with third parties, or to refund money to third parties under those
renegotiated contracts. Id. at 398-99 & n.13.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
B. Disgorgement Is Appropriate in This Case
Disgorgement is necessary to protect the public interest by
depriving KeySpan of the fruits of its ill-gotten gains and deterring
KeySpan and others from engaging in similar anticompetitive conduct in
the future. Absent disgorgement, KeySpan would be likely to retain all
the benefits of its anticompetitive conduct. A private lawsuit for
damages against KeySpan would face significant obstacles imposed by the
filed rate doctrine. See Keogh v. Chicago & N.W. Ry. Co., 260 U.S. 156
(1922). The filed rate doctrine also makes it unlikely that
disgorgement will lead to duplicative monetary remedies.
Furthermore, no other remedy would be as effective to fulfill the
remedial goals of the Sherman Act to ``prevent and restrain'' antitrust
violations. Injunctive relief would not be meaningful, given the facts
in this case. The specific agreement at issue--the KeySpan Swap--has,
by its terms, expired and the anticompetitive conduct is unlikely to
reoccur as KeySpan no longer owns the Ravenswood generation assets.
Disgorgement here will also serve to restrain KeySpan and others
from participating in similar anticompetitive conduct. Requiring
KeySpan to disgorge a portion of its ill-gotten gains from its recent
illegal behavior is the only effective way of achieving relief against
KeySpan, while sending a strong message to those considering similar
anticompetitive conduct.
IV. Remedies Available to Potential Private Litigants
Section 4 of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. 15, provides that any
person who has been injured as a result of conduct prohibited by the
antitrust laws may bring suit in federal court to recover three times
the damages the person has suffered, as well as costs and reasonable
attorneys' fees. Entry of the proposed Final Judgment will neither
impair nor assist the bringing of any private antitrust damage action.
Under the provisions of Section 5(a) of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C.
16(a), the proposed Final Judgment has no prima facie effect in
[[Page 9952]]
any subsequent private lawsuit that may be brought against KeySpan.
V. Procedures Available for Modification of the Proposed Final Judgment
The United States and the defendant have stipulated that the
proposed Final Judgment may be entered by the Court after compliance
with the provisions of the APPA, provided that the United States has
not withdrawn its consent. The APPA conditions entry upon the Court's
determination that the proposed Final Judgment is in the public
interest.
The APPA provides a period of at least sixty (60) days preceding
the effective date of the proposed Final Judgment within which any
person may submit to the United States written comments regarding the
proposed Final Judgment. Any person who wishes to comment should do so
within sixty (60) days of the date of publication of this Competitive
Impact Statement in the Federal Register, or the last date of
publication in a newspaper of the summary of this Competitive Impact
Statement, whichever is later. All comments received during this period
will be considered by the United States, which remains free to withdraw
its consent to the proposed Final Judgment at any time prior to the
Court's entry of judgment. The comments and the response of the United
States will be filed with the Court and published in the Federal
Register.
Written comments should be submitted to: Donna N. Kooperstein,
Chief, Transportation, Energy & Agriculture Section, Antitrust
Division, United States Department of Justice, 450 Fifth Street, NW.,
Suite 8000, Washington, DC 20530.
The proposed Final Judgment provides that the Court retains
jurisdiction over this action, and the parties may apply to the Court
for any order necessary or appropriate for the modification,
interpretation, or enforcement of the Final Judgment.
VI. Alternatives to the Proposed Final Judgment
The United States considered, as an alternative to the proposed
Final Judgment, a full trial on the merits against Defendant. The
United States is satisfied, however, that the disgorgement of profits
is an appropriate remedy in this matter. A disgorgement remedy should
deter Keyspan and others from engaging in similar conduct. Given the
facts of this case, the proposed Final Judgment would protect
competition as effectively as would any other equitable remedy
available through litigation, but avoids the time, expense, and
uncertainty of a full trial on the merits of the Complaint.
VII. Standard of Review Under the APPA for Proposed Final Judgment
The Clayton Act, as amended by the APPA, requires that proposed
consent judgments in antitrust cases brought by the United States be
subject to a sixty-day comment period, after which the court shall
determine whether entry of the proposed Final Judgment ``is in the
public interest.'' 15 U.S.C. 16(e)(1). In making that determination,
the court, in accordance with the statute as amended in 2004, is
required to consider:
(A) The competitive impact of such judgment, including
termination of alleged violations, provisions for enforcement and
modification, duration of relief sought, anticipated effects of
alternative remedies actually considered, whether its terms are
ambiguous, and any other competitive considerations bearing upon the
adequacy of such judgment that the court deems necessary to a
determination of whether the consent judgment is in the public
interest; and
(B) The impact of entry of such judgment upon competition in the
relevant market or markets, upon the public generally and
individuals alleging specific injury from the violations set forth
in the complaint including consideration of the public benefit, if
any, to be derived from a determination of the issues at trial.
15 U.S.C. 16(e)(1)(A) & (B). In considering these statutory factors,
the court's inquiry is necessarily a limited one as the United States
is entitled to ``broad discretion to settle with the defendant within
the reaches of the public interest.'' United States v. Microsoft Corp.,
56 F.3d 1448, 1461 (DC Cir. 1995); see generally United States v. SBC
Commc'ns, Inc., 489 F. Supp. 2d 1 (D.D.C. 2007) (assessing public
interest standard under the Tunney Act); United States v. InBev N.V./
S.A., 2009-2 Trade Cas. (CCH) ] 76,736, 2009 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 84787,
No. 08-1965 (JR), at *3 (D.D.C. Aug. 11, 2009) (noting that the court's
review of a consent judgment is limited and only inquires ``into
whether the government's determination that the proposed remedies will
cure the antitrust violations alleged in the complaint was reasonable,
and whether the mechanism to enforce the final judgment are clear and
manageable'').\4\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\4\ The 2004 amendments substituted ``shall'' for ``may'' in
directing relevant factors for a court to consider and amended the
list of factors to focus on competitive considerations and to
address potentially ambiguous judgment terms. Compare 15 U.S.C.
16(e) (2004), with 15 U.S.C. 16(e)(1) (2006); see also SBC Commc'ns,
489 F. Supp. 2d at 11 (concluding that the 2004 amendments
``effected minimal changes'' to Tunney Act review).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Under the APPA a court considers, among other things, the
relationship between the remedy secured and the specific allegations
set forth in the United States' complaint, whether the decree is
sufficiently clear, whether enforcement mechanisms are sufficient, and
whether the decree may positively harm third parties. See Microsoft, 56
F.3d at 1458-62. With respect to the adequacy of the relief secured by
the decree, a court may not ``engage in an unrestricted evaluation of
what relief would best serve the public.'' United States v. BNS, Inc.,
858 F.2d 456, 462 (9th Cir. 1988) (citing United States v. Bechtel
Corp., 648 F.2d 660, 666 (9th Cir. 1981)); see also Microsoft, 56 F.3d
at 1460-62; United States v. Alcoa, Inc., 152 F. Supp. 2d 37, 40
(D.D.C. 2001); InBev, 2009 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 84787, at *3. Courts have
held that:
[t]he balancing of competing social and political interests affected
by a proposed antitrust consent decree must be left, in the first
instance, to the discretion of the Attorney General. The court's
role in protecting the public interest is one of insuring that the
government has not breached its duty to the public in consenting to
the decree. The court is required to determine not whether a
particular decree is the one that will best serve society, but
whether the settlement is ``within the reaches of the public
interest.'' More elaborate requirements might undermine the
effectiveness of antitrust enforcement by consent decree.
Bechtel, 648 F.2d at 666 (emphasis added) (citations omitted).\5\ In
determining whether a proposed settlement is in the public interest, a
district court ``must accord deference to the government's predictions
about the efficacy of its remedies, and may not require that the
remedies perfectly match the alleged violations.'' SBC Commc'ns, 489 F.
Supp. 2d at 17; see also Microsoft, 56 F.3d at 1461 (noting the need
for courts to be ``deferential to the government's predictions as to
the effect of the proposed remedies''); United States v. Archer-
Daniels-Midland Co., 272 F. Supp. 2d 1, 6 (D.D.C. 2003) (noting that
the court should grant due respect to the United States' prediction as
to the effect of proposed remedies, its perception of the market
structure, and its views of the nature of the case).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\5\ Cf. BNS, 858 F.2d at 464 (holding that the court's
``ultimate authority under the [APPA] is limited to approving or
disapproving the consent decree''); United States v. Gillette Co.,
406 F. Supp. 713, 716 (D. Mass. 1975) (noting that, in this way, the
court is constrained to ``look at the overall picture not
hypercritically, nor with a microscope, but with an artist's
reducing glass''). See generally Microsoft, 56 F.3d at 1461
(discussing whether ``the remedies [obtained in the decree are] so
inconsonant with the allegations charged as to fall outside of the
`reaches of the public interest' '').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
[[Page 9953]]
Courts have greater flexibility in approving proposed consent
decrees than in crafting their own decrees following a finding of
liability in a litigated matter. ``[A] proposed decree must be approved
even if it falls short of the remedy the court would impose on its own,
as long as it falls within the range of acceptability or is `within the
reaches of public interest.' '' United States v. Am. Tel. & Tel. Co.,
552 F. Supp. 131, 151 (D.D.C. 1982) (citations omitted) (quoting United
States v. Gillette Co., 406 F. Supp. 713, 716 (D. Mass. 1975)), aff'd
sub nom. Maryland v. United States, 460 U.S. 1001 (1983); see also
United States v. Alcan Aluminum Ltd., 605 F. Supp. 619, 622 (W.D. Ky.
1985) (approving the consent decree even though the court would have
imposed a greater remedy). To meet this standard, the United States
``need only provide a factual basis for concluding that the settlements
are reasonably adequate remedies for the alleged harms.'' SBC Commc'ns,
489 F. Supp. 2d at 17.
Moreover, the court's role under the APPA is limited to reviewing
the remedy in relationship to the violations that the United States has
alleged in its Complaint, and does not authorize the court to
``construct [its] own hypothetical case and then evaluate the decree
against that case.'' Microsoft, 56 F.3d at 1459; see also InBev, 2009
U.S. Dist. LEXIS 84787, at *20 (``[T]he `public interest' is not to be
measured by comparing the violations alleged in the complaint against
those the court believes could have, or even should have, been
alleged.''). Because the ``court's authority to review the decree
depends entirely on the government's exercising its prosecutorial
discretion by bringing a case in the first place,'' it follows that
``the court is only authorized to review the decree itself,'' and not
to ``effectively redraft the complaint'' to inquire into other matters
that the United States did not pursue. Microsoft, 56 F.3d. at 1459-60.
Courts ``cannot look beyond the complaint in making the public interest
determination unless the complaint is drafted so narrowly as to make a
mockery of judicial power.'' SBC Commc'ns, 489 F. Supp. 2d at 15.
In its 2004 amendments, Congress made clear its intent to preserve
the practical benefits of utilizing consent decrees in antitrust
enforcement, adding the unambiguous instruction that ``[n]othing in
this section shall be construed to require the court to conduct an
evidentiary hearing or to require the court to permit anyone to
intervene.'' 15 U.S.C. 16(e)(2). This language effectuates what
Congress intended when it enacted the Tunney Act in 1974, as Senator
Tunney explained: ``[t]he court is nowhere compelled to go to trial or
to engage in extended proceedings which might have the effect of
vitiating the benefits of prompt and less costly settlement through the
consent decree process.'' 119 Cong. Rec. 24,598 (1973) (statement of
Senator Tunney). Rather, the procedure for the public interest
determination is left to the discretion of the court, with the
recognition that the court's ``scope of review remains sharply
proscribed by precedent and the nature of Tunney Act proceedings.'' SBC
Commc'ns, 489 F. Supp. 2d at 11.\6\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\6\ See United States v. Enova Corp., 107 F. Supp. 2d 10, 17
(D.D.C. 2000) (noting that the ``Tunney Act expressly allows the
court to make its public interest determination on the basis of the
competitive impact statement and response to comments alone'');
United States v. Mid-Am. Dairymen, Inc., 1977-1 Trade Cas. (CCH) ]
61,508, at 71,980 (W.D. Mo. 1977) (``Absent a showing of corrupt
failure of the government to discharge its duty, the Court, in
making its public interest finding, should * * * carefully consider
the explanations of the government in the competitive impact
statement and its responses to comments in order to determine
whether those explanations are reasonable under the
circumstances.''); S. Rep. No. 93-298, 93d Cong., 1st Sess., at 6
(1973) (``Where the public interest can be meaningfully evaluated
simply on the basis of briefs and oral arguments, that is the
approach that should be utilized.'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
VIII. Determinative Documents
There are no determinative materials or documents within the
meaning of the APPA that the United States considered in formulating
the proposed Final Judgment.
Dated: February 22, 2010.
Respectfully submitted,
For Plaintiff The United States of America
David E. Altschuler,
Jade Alice Eaton,
Trial Attorneys, United States Department of Justice, Antitrust
Division, Transportation, Energy & Agriculture Section, 450 5th
Street, NW., Suite 8000, Washington, DC 20530, Telephone: (202) 307-
6316, david.altschuler@usdoj.gov, jade.eaton@usdoj.gov.
[FR Doc. 2010-4545 Filed 3-3-10; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 4410-11-P