Wholesale Competition in Regions With Organized Electric Markets, 37776-37801 [E9-17364]
Download as PDF
37776
Federal Register / Vol. 74, No. 144 / Wednesday, July 29, 2009 / Rules and Regulations
DEPARTMENT OF ENERGY
Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission
18 CFR Part 35
[Docket No. RM07–19–001; Order No.
719–A]
Wholesale Competition in Regions
With Organized Electric Markets
July 16, 2009.
AGENCY: Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission, DOE.
ACTION: Final rule; order on rehearing.
SUMMARY: In this order on rehearing, the
Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
(Commission) affirms its basic
determinations in Order No. 719,
Wholesale Competition in Regions with
Organized Electric Markets, which
amended Commission regulations to
improve the operation of organized
wholesale electric markets in four areas:
Demand response, including pricing
during periods of operating reserve
shortage; long-term power contracting;
market-monitoring policies; and the
responsiveness of RTOs and ISOs to
their customers and other stakeholders.
This order denies in part and grants in
part rehearing and clarification
regarding certain provisions of Order
No. 719.
DATES: Effective Date: This is effective
on August 28, 2009.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
Russell Profozich (Technical
Information), Office of Energy Market
Regulation, Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission, 888 First Street, NE.,
Washington, DC 20426.
Russell.Profozich@ferc.gov. (202) 502–
6478.
Tina Ham (Legal Information), Office of
the General Counsel, Federal Energy
Regulatory Commission, 888 First
Street, NE., Washington, DC 20426.
Tina.Ham@ferc.gov. (202) 502–6224.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION:
mstockstill on DSKH9S0YB1PROD with RULES2
TABLE OF CONTENTS
I. Introduction .........................................................................................................................................................................................
A. Summary of Order No. 719 .......................................................................................................................................................
B. Requests for Rehearing ...............................................................................................................................................................
II. Discussion ..........................................................................................................................................................................................
A. Demand Response and Pricing During Periods of Operating Reserve Shortages in Organized Markets .............................
1. Ancillary Services Provided by Demand Response Providers ..........................................................................................
a. Request for Rehearing ...................................................................................................................................................
b. Commission Determination ..........................................................................................................................................
2. Aggregation of Retail Customers .........................................................................................................................................
a. Requests for Rehearing .................................................................................................................................................
b. Commission Determination ..........................................................................................................................................
3. Market Rules Governing Price Formation During Periods of Operating Reserve Shortage ............................................
a. Requests for Rehearing .................................................................................................................................................
b. Commission Determination ..........................................................................................................................................
B. Long-Term Power Contracting in Organized Markets ..............................................................................................................
1. Hedging Instruments ............................................................................................................................................................
a. Request for Rehearing ...................................................................................................................................................
b. Commission Determination ..........................................................................................................................................
2. Structural Issues ...................................................................................................................................................................
a. Request for Rehearing ...................................................................................................................................................
b. Commission Determination ..........................................................................................................................................
C. Market-Monitoring Policies ........................................................................................................................................................
1. Market Mitigation ................................................................................................................................................................
a. Requests for Rehearing .................................................................................................................................................
b. Commission Determination ..........................................................................................................................................
2. Relationship Between Internal and External MMU ...........................................................................................................
a. Requests for Rehearing .................................................................................................................................................
b. Commission Determination ..........................................................................................................................................
3. State Access to MMU Information ......................................................................................................................................
a. Requests for Rehearing .................................................................................................................................................
b. Commission Determination ..........................................................................................................................................
4. Offer and Bid Data ...............................................................................................................................................................
a. Requests for Rehearing or Clarification .......................................................................................................................
b. Commission Determination ..........................................................................................................................................
5. Ethics Provisions ..................................................................................................................................................................
a. Request for Rehearing or Clarification .........................................................................................................................
b. Commission Determination ..........................................................................................................................................
6. Referral of Market Design Flaws .........................................................................................................................................
D. Responsiveness of RTOs and ISOs to Customers and Other Stakeholders ............................................................................
1. Criteria for Responsiveness .................................................................................................................................................
a. Requests for Rehearing .................................................................................................................................................
b. Commission Determination ..........................................................................................................................................
2. Hybrid Boards ......................................................................................................................................................................
a. Requests for Rehearing .................................................................................................................................................
b. Commission Determination ..........................................................................................................................................
3. Mission Statements ..............................................................................................................................................................
a. Requests for Rehearing .................................................................................................................................................
b. Commission Determination ..........................................................................................................................................
III. Document Availability .....................................................................................................................................................................
IV. Effective Date ....................................................................................................................................................................................
Regulatory Text
VerDate Nov<24>2008
20:07 Jul 28, 2009
Jkt 217001
PO 00000
Frm 00002
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
E:\FR\FM\29JYR2.SGM
29JYR2
1
2
10
13
13
13
15
16
17
18
41
72
74
93
107
108
109
110
111
112
117
123
127
129
133
138
139
141
144
145
146
151
152
156
160
161
164
167
171
172
173
178
184
186
189
192
193
194
195
198
Federal Register / Vol. 74, No. 144 / Wednesday, July 29, 2009 / Rules and Regulations
128 FERC ¶ 61,059
Before Commissioners: Jon Wellinghoff,
Chairman; Suedeen G. Kelly, Marc Spitzer,
and Philip D. Moeller.
I. Introduction
1. On October 17, 2008, the
Commission issued a Final Rule 1
establishing reforms to improve the
operation of organized wholesale
electric power markets 2 and amended
its regulations under the Federal Power
Act (FPA) in the areas of: (1) Demand
response, including pricing during
periods of operating reserve shortage; (2)
long-term power contracting; (3) marketmonitoring policies; and (4) the
responsiveness of RTOs and ISOs to
their customers and other stakeholders.3
The Commission stated that these
reforms are intended to improve
wholesale competition to protect
consumers in several ways: By
providing more supply options,
encouraging new entry and innovation,
spurring deployment of new
technologies, removing barriers to
comparable treatment of demand
response, improving operating
performance, exerting downward
pressure on costs, and shifting risk away
from consumers.
mstockstill on DSKH9S0YB1PROD with RULES2
A. Summary of Order No. 719
2. In the area of demand response, the
Commission required each RTO and ISO
to: (1) Accept bids from demand
response resources in RTOs’ and ISOs’
markets for certain ancillary services on
a basis comparable to other resources;
(2) eliminate, during a system
emergency, a charge to a buyer that
takes less electric energy in the real-time
market than it purchased in the dayahead market; (3) in certain
circumstances, permit an aggregator of
1 Wholesale Competition in Regions with
Organized Electric Markets, Order No. 719, 73 FR
64,100 (Oct. 28, 2008), FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,281
(2008) (Order No. 719 or Final Rule).
2 Organized market regions are areas of the
country in which a regional transmission
organization (RTO) or independent system operator
(ISO) operates day-ahead and/or real-time energy
markets. The following Commission-approved
RTOs and ISOs have organized markets: PJM
Interconnection, LLC (PJM); New York Independent
System Operator, Inc. (NYISO); Midwest
Independent Transmission System Operator, Inc.
(Midwest ISO); ISO New England, Inc. (ISO New
England); California Independent System Operator
Corp. (CAISO); and Southwest Power Pool, Inc.
(SPP).
3 In this rulemaking, the Commission also issued
an advanced notice of proposed rulemaking,
Wholesale Competition in Regions with Organized
Electric Markets, Advance Notice of Proposed
Rulemaking, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 32,617 (2007)
(ANOPR) and a notice of proposed rulemaking,
Wholesale Competition in Regions with Organized
Electric Markets, Notice of Proposed Rulemaking,
FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 32,628 (2008) (NOPR).
VerDate Nov<24>2008
18:36 Jul 28, 2009
Jkt 217001
retail customers (ARC) to bid demand
response on behalf of retail customers
directly into the organized energy
market; and (4) modify their market
rules, as necessary, to allow the marketclearing price, during periods of
operating reserve shortage, to reach a
level that rebalances supply and
demand so as to maintain reliability
while providing sufficient provisions for
mitigating market power.4
3. Additionally, the Commission
recognized that further reforms may be
necessary to eliminate barriers to
demand response in the future. To that
end, the Commission required each RTO
or ISO to assess and report on any
remaining barriers to comparable
treatment of demand response resources
that are within the Commission’s
jurisdiction. The Commission further
required each RTO’s or ISO’s
Independent Market Monitor to submit
a report describing its views on its
RTO’s or ISO’s assessment to the
Commission.5
4. With regard to long-term power
contracting, the Commission required
each RTO and ISO to dedicate a portion
of its Web sites for market participants
to post offers to buy or sell power on a
long-term basis.
5. To improve market monitoring, the
Commission required each RTO and ISO
to provide its Market Monitoring Unit
(MMU) with access to market data,
resources and personnel sufficient to
carry out their duties, and required the
MMU to report directly to the RTO or
ISO board of directors.6 In addition, the
Commission required that the MMU’s
functions include: (1) Identifying
ineffective market rules and
recommending proposed rules and tariff
changes; (2) reviewing and reporting on
the performance of the wholesale
markets to the RTO or ISO, the
Commission, and other interested
entities; and (3) notifying appropriate
Commission staff of instances in which
a market participant’s or the RTO’s or
ISO’s behavior may require
investigation.
6. The Commission also took the
following actions with regard to MMUs:
(1) Expanded the list of recipients of
MMU recommendations regarding rule
and tariff changes, and broadened the
scope of behavior to be reported to the
Commission; (2) modified MMU
4 Order No. 719, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,281 at
P 4, 15.
5 Id. P 274.
6 The use of the phrase ‘‘board of directors’’
herein also includes the board of managers, board
of governors, and similar entities. An internal MMU
in a hybrid structure may report to management so
long as it does not perform any of the core MMU
functions.
PO 00000
Frm 00003
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
37777
participation in tariff administration
and market mitigation, required each
RTO and ISO to include ethics
standards for MMU employees in its
tariff, and required each RTO and ISO
to consolidate all its MMU provisions in
one section of its tariff; and (3)
expanded the dissemination of MMU
market information to a broader
constituency, with reports made on a
more frequent basis than in the past,
and reduced the time period before
energy market bid and offer data are
released to the public.
7. Finally, the Commission
established an obligation for each RTO
and ISO to establish a means for
customers and other stakeholders to
have a form of direct access to the RTO
or ISO board of directors, and thereby,
increase its responsiveness to customers
and other stakeholders. The
Commission stated that it will assess
each RTO’s or ISO’s compliance filing
using four responsiveness criteria: (1)
Inclusiveness; (2) fairness in balancing
diverse interests; (3) representation of
minority positions; and (4) ongoing
responsiveness.
8. The Commission stated in the Final
Rule that its actions in these four areas
are consistent with its duty to improve
the operation of wholesale power
markets.7 The Commission also
reiterated its statement from the
underlying Notice of Proposed
Rulemaking that the reforms addressed
in this proceeding do not represent the
Commission’s final effort to improve the
functioning of competitive markets for
the benefit of consumers. Rather, the
Commission will continue to evaluate
other specific reforms that may
strengthen organized markets.8
9. In each of the four areas, the Final
Rule required each RTO or ISO to
consult with its stakeholders and make
a compliance filing that explains how
its existing practices comply with the
Final Rule’s reforms, or its plans to
attain compliance.9
B. Requests for Rehearing
10. The following entities have filed
timely requests for rehearing or for
clarification of Order No. 719: American
Electric Power Corporation (AEP);
American Public Power Association
(APPA) and California Municipal
Utilities Association (CMUA) (jointly,
APPA–CMUA); APPA, CMUA and
National Rural Electric Cooperative
Association (NRECA) (collectively, Joint
Petitioners); Illinois Commerce
7 Order No. 719, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,281 at
P 2.
8 Id. P 14.
9 Id. P 8, 578–83.
E:\FR\FM\29JYR2.SGM
29JYR2
37778
Federal Register / Vol. 74, No. 144 / Wednesday, July 29, 2009 / Rules and Regulations
mstockstill on DSKH9S0YB1PROD with RULES2
Commission; Coalition of Midwest
Transmission Customers, NEPOOL
Industrial Customer Coalition, and PJM
Industrial Customers Coalition
(collectively, Industrial Coalitions);
Minnesota Public Utilities Commission
(Minnesota PUC); National Association
of Regulatory Utility Commissioners
(NARUC); Public Utilities Commission
of Ohio (Ohio PUC); Old Dominion
Electric Cooperative (Old Dominion);
Potomac Economics, Ltd. (Potomac
Economics); Pennsylvania Public
Utilities Commission (Pennsylvania
PUC); Sacramento Municipal Utility
District (SMUD); Transmission Access
Policy Study Group (TAPS); and Public
Service Commission of Wisconsin
(Wisconsin PSC). New York
Independent System Operator, Inc.
(NYISO) submitted an untimely request
for clarification. Additionally, PJM
Interconnection, L.L.C. filed a motion
for leave to respond and response to the
requests for rehearing. Joint Petitioners
filed an answer to PJM’s motion.10
11. We dismiss NYISO’s untimely
request for clarification of Order No. 719
because it is, in essence, an untimely
request for rehearing. The courts have
repeatedly recognized that the time
period within which a party may file a
petition for rehearing of a Commission
order is statutorily established at 30
days by section 313(a) of the FPA11 and
that the Commission has no discretion
to extend that deadline.12 Accordingly,
the Commission has long held that it
lacks the authority to consider requests
for rehearing filed more than 30 days
after issuance of a Commission order.13
12. Rule 713(d)(1) of the
Commission’s Rules of Practice and
Procedure, 18 CFR 385.713(d)(1) (2008),
prohibits answers to requests for
rehearing. Accordingly, we reject PJM’s
motion to respond to requests for
rehearing and Joint Petitioners’ answer
to PJM’s motion.
10 Additionally, Monitoring Analytics, LLC filed
an out-of-time motion to intervene in this
proceeding, but did not seek rehearing.
11 16 U.S.C 825l.
12 See, e.g., City of Campbell v. FERC, 770 F.2d
1180, 1183 (D.C. Cir. 1985) (‘‘The 30-day time
requirement of [the FPA] is as much a part of the
jurisdictional threshold as the mandate to file for
a rehearing.’’); Boston Gas Co. v. FERC, 575 F.2d
975, 977–98, 979 (1st Cir. 1978) (describing
identical rehearing provision of the Natural Gas Act
as ‘‘a tightly structured and formal provision.
Neither the Commission nor the courts are given
any form of jurisdictional discretion.’’).
13 See, e.g., Arkansas Power & Light Co., 19 FERC
¶ 61,115 at 61,217–18, reh’g denied, 20 FERC
¶ 61,013, at 61,034 (1982). See also Public Serv. Co.
of New Hampshire, 56 FERC ¶ 61,105, at 61,403
(1991); CMS Midland, Inc., 56 FERC ¶ 61,177, at
61,623 (1991).
VerDate Nov<24>2008
18:36 Jul 28, 2009
Jkt 217001
II. Discussion
A. Demand Response and Pricing
During Periods of Operating Reserve
Shortages in Organized Markets
1. Ancillary Services Provided by
Demand Response Providers
13. The Final Rule required each RTO
or ISO to accept bids from demand
response resources, on a basis
comparable to any other resources, for
ancillary services that are acquired in a
competitive bidding process, if the
demand response resources: (1) Are
technically capable of providing the
ancillary service and meet the necessary
technical requirements; and (2) submit a
bid under the generally-applicable
bidding rules at or below the marketclearing price, unless the laws or
regulations of the relevant electric retail
regulatory authority do not permit a
retail customer to participate. All
accepted bids would receive the marketclearing price.14 The Commission
determined that these requirements
would remove barriers to the
comparable treatment of demand-side
and supply-side resources.
14. In the Final Rule, in response to
commenters who asked the Commission
to allow energy efficiency resources to
bid into the organized markets, the
Commission recognized the value of
energy efficiency resources. The
Commission stated that it has not
excluded from eligibility as a provider
of ancillary services any type of
resource that is technically capable of
providing the ancillary service,
including energy efficiency resources.
However, because this proceeding did
not propose to include energy efficiency
resources as providers of competitively
procured ancillary services, the
Commission stated that it did not have
an adequate record to address this
issue.15
a. Request for Rehearing
15. Pennsylvania PUC asserts that the
Commission should uphold its
‘‘comparable terms and conditions’’
principle regarding acceptance of
demand response resources for ancillary
services by requiring each RTO and ISO
to file tariff provisions defining energy
efficiency resources as resources
qualified to bid into energy markets and
ancillary services markets upon such
terms and conditions as the RTO or ISO
may propose. In addition, it asks the
Commission to require each RTO and
ISO to supply arguments and adequate
record evidence in support of such a
14 Order No. 719, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,281 at
P 47.
15 Id. P 56.
PO 00000
Frm 00004
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
filing so that the Commission can
determine whether energy efficiency
resources are being accepted on a
comparable basis with any other
resources qualified to bid into energy
markets and ancillary services
markets.16
b. Commission Determination
16. The Final Rule does not exclude
from eligibility any type of resource that
is technically capable of providing an
ancillary service, and therefore we
disagree with Pennsylvania PUC that
the Final Rule leaves in place a barrier
to the use of energy efficiency resources
that we must remedy on rehearing. An
RTO or ISO is free to work with its
stakeholders and incorporate energy
efficiency resources into its markets on
a basis that is appropriate for its
region.17
2. Aggregation of Retail Customers
17. Order No. 719 required RTOs and
ISOs to amend their market rules as
necessary to permit an ARC to bid
demand response on behalf of retail
customers directly into the RTO’s or
ISO’s organized markets, unless the
laws or regulations of the relevant
electric retail regulatory authority do
not permit a retail customer to
participate. The Commission
determined that allowing an ARC to act
as an intermediary for many small retail
loads that cannot individually
participate in the organized market
would reduce a barrier to demand
response.18 The Commission directed
RTOs and ISOs to submit compliance
filings to propose amendments to their
tariffs or otherwise demonstrate how
their existing tariffs and market rules
comply with the Final Rule.19
a. Requests for Rehearing
i. Commission Jurisdiction
18. Several petitioners assert that the
Final Rule’s ARC requirements exceed
the Commission’s statutory authority
under the FPA.20 TAPS and Joint
Petitioners state that under section
201(a) of the FPA, the Commission’s
jurisdiction is limited to the
transmission of electric energy in
interstate commerce and the sale of such
energy at wholesale in interstate
16 Pennsylvania
17 Order
PUC at 4.
No. 719, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,281 at
P 276.
18 Id. P 154.
19 Id. P 163.
20 See, e.g., TAPS at 9–13; Joint Petitioners at 18–
23; NARUC at 3. NARUC states that it incorporates
by reference the arguments presented on this issue
by Joint Petitioners’ request for rehearing. NARUC
at 5.
E:\FR\FM\29JYR2.SGM
29JYR2
Federal Register / Vol. 74, No. 144 / Wednesday, July 29, 2009 / Rules and Regulations
commerce.21 They argue that a retail
customer’s reduction of energy
consumption is neither a wholesale sale
of electric energy nor transmission in
interstate commerce, and that retail
sales are sales of electric energy to end
users that are not sales for resale.22 Joint
Petitioners add that a promise not to
consume electric energy at a particular
time is a product not covered by the
plain language of the FPA.23 TAPS,
therefore, concludes that the
Commission lacks jurisdiction to modify
retail electricity sales by effectively
establishing a new rule that authorizes
retail customers purchasing electricity
(or non-consumption) to resell that
electricity into wholesale markets,
either directly or through a third
party.24
19. Joint Petitioners argue that the
Final Rule’s ARC requirement violates
the separation of Federal and State
jurisdiction because it effectively
requires public power systems and
cooperatives to take affirmative action to
consider retail aggregation issues.25
Joint Petitioners state that the majority
of these systems do not have laws or
regulations addressing end-use
customer aggregation. They argue that
the Commission has no jurisdiction to
require such affirmative action because
it is beyond the scope of its legal
authority set out in the FPA.
20. Additionally, TAPS argues that
States’ and relevant electric retail
regulatory authorities’ laws and
regulations do not grant retail customers
either the title or a contract right to
resell retail electricity (or any such nonconsumption). In that respect, TAPS
argues that the Final Rule intrudes into
retail electric service rates by requiring
RTOs and ISOs to accept demand
response bids that may be prohibited by
State law, without first obtaining
confirmation that such transactions are
permitted by the relevant electric retail
regulatory authority. Joint Petitioners
also note that Congress acknowledged
that State and local regulation extends
to such consumption decisions when it
directed State regulators and non-
mstockstill on DSKH9S0YB1PROD with RULES2
21 16
U.S.C. 824(a).
22 TAPS at 11–12; Joint Petitioners at 18–19
(citing United States v. Public Utils. Comm’n of
California, 345 U.S. 295, 303 (1953); Federal Power
Comm’n v. Southern California Edison Co., 376
U.S. 202, 216 (1964)).
23 Joint Petitioners at 19.
24 TAPS at 12–13 (citing N.Y. v. FERC, 535 U.S.
1, 20 (2002); FPC v. Conway Corp., 426 U.S. 271,
276–77 (1976)).
25 Joint Petitioners at 13, 18 (citing Northern
States Power Co., 176 F.3d 1090, 1096 (8th Cir.
1999), reh’g en banc denied 1999 U.S. App. LEXIS
23493 (8th Cir. Sept. 1, 1999), cert. denied sub
nom.; Enron Power Mktg., Inc. v. Northern States
Power Co., 528 U.S. 1182 (2000); Atlantic City
Electric Co. v. FERC, 295 F.3d 1, 8 (D.C. Cir. 2002)).
VerDate Nov<24>2008
18:36 Jul 28, 2009
Jkt 217001
regulated utilities to consider
implementing demand response
programs at the State and local level in
2007 amendments to the Public Utility
Regulatory Policies Act (PURPA).26
Further, they argue that the Commission
failed to explain how it has jurisdiction
over the demand response programs of
public power systems and cooperatives
that are not public utilities, and are
therefore exempt, under FPA section
201(f), from the Commission’s FPA
section 206 authority 27 Joint Petitioners
contend that the Commission cannot
‘‘indirectly’’ claim jurisdiction over
non-jurisdictional entities.28
21. Ohio PUC argues that third-party
aggregation bids should be subject to
State regulatory authority or approval.29
While it agrees that ARCs should be
permitted to aggregate smaller loads, it
asserts that retail customers and their
representatives should not be classified
as wholesale customers subject to the
Commission’s jurisdiction simply
because they provide demand response
to the wholesale market. Therefore,
Ohio PUC contends that the Final Rule
should have acknowledged that all
contracts by third-party ARCs are
subject to State retail jurisdiction and
should be subject to State commission
26 Section 532 of the Energy Independence and
Security Act of 2007 amended PURPA section
111(d) by adding a new standard that requires
consideration of rate design modifications to
promote energy efficiency investments. 16 U.S.C.
2621(d). To assist in this effort, Joint Petitioners
note that APPA and NRECA commissioned a
reference manual regarding the new requirements.
Reference Manual and Procedures for
Implementation of the PURPA Standards in the
Energy Independence and Security Act of 2007, Dr.
Ken Rose and Michael Murphy, available at
https://www.naruc.org/Publications/
EISAStandardsManualFINAL.pdf. Joint Petitioners
argue that efforts to have distribution cooperatives
or public power distribution systems invest in a
demand response program after considering these
new federal PURPA standards could be undermined
by the activities of third-party ARCs seeking to take
the demand response of the public power or
cooperative system’s retail customers directly to the
wholesale market. Joint Petitioners at 21.
27 16 U.S.C. 824(f). Joint Petitioners at 21 (citing
Bonneville Power Administration, et al. v. FERC,
422 F.3d 908, 915 (9th Cir. 2005).
28 Joint Petitioners state that the ‘‘Commission
cannot bootstrap jurisdiction over * * * nonjurisdictional entities simply by pointing to
jurisdiction over their retail customers’’ and that the
Commission ‘‘cannot do indirectly what it cannot
do directly.’’ Joint Petitioners at 21 (citing
Richmond Power & Light v. FERC, 574 F.2d 610,
620 (D.C. Cir. 1978); Altamont Gas Transmission
Co., et al. v. FERC, 92 F.3d 1239, 1248 (D.C. Cir.
1996); and Williams Gas Processing-Gulf Coast Co.,
L.P. v. FERC, 331 F.3d 1011, 1022 (D.C. Cir. 2003)).
29 Ohio PUC at 6–7 (stating that ‘‘it is the
prerogative of each individual state commission to
decide to what extent it will expose its retail
customers to the wholesale market, and what, if
any, advanced technology (i.e., smart meters) its
retail customers desire and wish to purchase’’).
PO 00000
Frm 00005
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
37779
approval prior to providing demand
response resources to an RTO or ISO.30
22. Joint Petitioners ask the
Commission to rule on rehearing that in
the case of public power systems and
cooperative utilities, RTOs and ISOs
should not accept ARCs’ demand
response bids unless a system’s relevant
electric retail regulatory authority
affirmatively informs the RTO or ISO
that it permits aggregation by third-party
ARCs.31 They believe that this approach
would allow the Commission to
encourage demand response while still
respecting the State and local retail
regulatory authorities. Similarly, TAPS
urges the Commission to modify the
opt-out structure of the ARC
requirements by changing it to an optin structure to remedy the jurisdictional
defect and to avoid undue burden to
small relevant electric retail regulatory
authorities.32 TAPS argues that such
modifications would invite relevant
electric retail regulatory authorities to
contact the RTO or ISO to provide the
necessary notification. Joint Petitioners
and TAPS state that absent a
notification that permission has been
granted, the RTO or ISO should
presume that sales of demand response
in RTO or ISO markets are not
permitted.
23. Additionally, TAPS argues that
ARCs and other entities bidding
demand response into RTO or ISO
markets should be required to certify
that their sales are permitted. It asserts
that it would be difficult for RTOs or
ISOs or relevant electric retail regulatory
authorities to identify, independently,
whether improper sales or aggregation
occur. It states that entities bidding
demand response into the RTO or ISO
wholesale markets are in the best
position to identify the specific retail
loads and customers involved and to
verify that such bids are permitted by
the relevant electric retail regulatory
authority. It notes that network
customers must provide certification to
support designation of network
resources.33 Similarly, individual retail
30 Id. at 6. The Wisconsin PSC states that it adopts
Ohio PUC’s arguments on this issue. Wisconsin PSC
at 2. NARUC states that it incorporates by reference
the arguments presented on this issue by Ohio
PUC’s request for rehearing. NARUC at 5.
31 Joint Petitioners at 15–16.
32 Specifically, TAPS suggests that the
Commission modify the regulatory text to replace:
(1) The ‘‘unless’’ clause of 18 CFR
35.28(g)(1)(B)(3)(iii) with ‘‘if the relevant electric
retail regulatory authority expressly permits a retail
customer to participate’’; and (2) the ‘‘unless’’
clause of 18 CFR 35.28(g)(1)(i)(A) with ‘‘if permitted
by the laws or regulations of the relevant electric
retail regulatory authority.’’ TAPS at 28.
33 Id. at 31. TAPS notes that under Order No. 890,
network customers must attest, for each network
E:\FR\FM\29JYR2.SGM
Continued
29JYR2
37780
Federal Register / Vol. 74, No. 144 / Wednesday, July 29, 2009 / Rules and Regulations
mstockstill on DSKH9S0YB1PROD with RULES2
customers and ARCs should be required
to certify that their bids and sales of
demand response into wholesale
markets are permitted under applicable
law, and submission by such entities of
ineligible demand response bids should
be a tariff violation.
24. Further, AEP notes that the Final
Rule permits retail customers to
participate in an RTO’s or ISO’s demand
program unless the laws or regulations
of the relevant electric retail regulatory
authority do not permit a retail
customer to participate. It seeks
clarification as to ‘‘whether this
exception applies to [s]tate commissionapproved tariff provisions that prohibit
sales for resale.’’ 34
25. AEP asserts that a State
commission in a non-retail choice State
should have the opportunity to fully
consider and determine whether an
RTO or ISO wholesale demand response
program is appropriate for that State.
AEP is concerned that RTOs and ISOs
may interpret the Final Rule’s language
on the ARC requirement to mean that
RTOs and ISOs may proceed with
demand response programs in States
where retail customers are provided
with State regulated average embedded
cost rates, unless States specifically opt
out of an RTO’s or ISO’s wholesale
demand response program. AEP argues
that such an interpretation would allow:
(1) Non-choice retail customers with
average embedded cost rates an
opportunity to arbitrage their load
through sales into wholesale markets to
the detriment of remaining retail
customers in that State; and (2) an RTO
or ISO to set new policy without any
consideration of unintended
consequences to retail customers.35
26. Additionally, AEP notes that a
retail customer’s action could be
considered a ‘‘resale’’ when the
customer purchases electric service
under a retail tariff and then receives
compensation for bidding its load into
the wholesale market through a demand
response program. Therefore, AEP asks
that the Commission either clarify the
Final Rule to provide that participation
in wholesale demand response
programs by retail customers does not
constitute a ‘‘sale for resale,’’ or require
that retail customers seeking to
resource identified for designation, that: (1) The
transmission customer owns or has committed to
purchase the designated network resource; and (2)
the designated network resource meets the
requirements for designated network resources.
Preventing Undue Discrimination and Preference in
Transmission Service, Order No. 890, FERC Stats.
& Regs. ¶ 31,241, order on reh’g, Order No. 890–
A, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,261 (2007), order on
reh’g, Order No. 890–B, 123 FERC ¶ 61,299 (2008).
34 AEP at 1.
35 Id. at 2.
VerDate Nov<24>2008
18:36 Jul 28, 2009
Jkt 217001
participate in such programs seek such
an exception from the applicable State
commission.36
ii. Burden on Small Entities and
Regulatory Flexibility Analysis
27. Several petitioners state that
requiring the relevant electric retail
regulatory authorities of each public
system to consider some type of
affirmative action on the ARC issue
imposes a significant burden on them.37
For example, TAPS argues that the Final
Rule requires every relevant electric
retail regulatory authority, regardless of
size, to address whether demand
response sales may be bid into an RTO
or ISO market and whether ARCs may
aggregate demand response within the
regulatory authority’s jurisdiction.38
Joint Petitioners argue that, for the
majority of retail regulatory authorities,
this would be a substantial undertaking
requiring a huge learning curve to
become familiar with the process and
consequently resulting in a lengthy
legislative process.39 Similarly, TAPS
asserts that it is a huge undertaking for
the city council of every municipal
electric system in an RTO or ISO to
expressly address this issue through
legislation or regulation.40 TAPS adds
that the Final Rule effectively leaves
enforcement responsibility with the
relevant electric retail regulatory
authority by requiring these entities to
monitor and challenge any bids and
certifications by ARCs that are not
permitted within their jurisdiction.
28. Joint Petitioners argue that the
Commission erred in certifying that
Order No. 719 will not have a
significant economic impact on a
substantial number of small entities and
certifying that the Final Rule complies
with the Regulatory Flexibility Act of
1980 (RFA).41 Joint Petitioners assert
at 2–3.
states that it incorporates by reference
the arguments presented on this issue by Joint
Petitioners’ request for rehearing. NARUC at 5.
38 TAPS at 25–26.
39 For example, Joint Petitioners note that CMUA
explained in its NOPR comments that the
presumption of implicit authority to allow ARCs to
aggregate bids makes no sense in California because
direct access was suspended following the 2000–01
market crisis. Accordingly, California no longer has
laws or regulations dealing with new direct access,
and CMUA has not restructured its retail rules and
ordinances with retail choice as an option.
Therefore, Joint Petitioners state that to now require
an affirmative action would be a substantial
undertaking. Joint Petitioners at 16–17.
40 TAPS notes that its members include: (1) AMP–
Ohio, serving 123 municipal electric systems in
Midwest ISO and PJM; (2) Indiana Municipal Power
Agency, serving 51 municipal electric systems in
Midwest ISO and PJM; and (3) Wisconsin Public
Power, serving 50 municipal electric systems in
Midwest ISO. TAPS at 26.
41 5 U.S.C. 601–12.
PO 00000
36 Id.
37 NARUC
Frm 00006
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
that the reasoning underlying this
certification is invalid and therefore
seek rehearing.42 They emphasize that,
unless public power systems and
cooperatives take affirmative action to
enact the necessary law or regulation,
relevant electric retail authorities could
risk having their public power systems’
demand response programs undermined
and day-to-day system operations
disrupted by ARCs’ demand response
activities. They reiterate that it would be
a significant burden for relevant electric
retail regulatory authorities of over
1,300 public power systems and 850
distribution cooperatives to take up this
issue. Accordingly, Joint Petitioners
maintain that the Final Rule’s ARC
requirement would result in a
significant adverse impact on a
substantial number of small entities
and, therefore, the Commission is
required to provide a certification under
the RFA.
29. TAPS also argues that by imposing
responsibilities on small entities, the
Final Rule ignores the RFA’s
requirements.43 TAPS disputes the
Commission’s cite to American
Trucking Associations, Inc. v. EPA
(American Trucking Associations) 44 to
support its position in the Final Rule
that the RFA analysis is not required. It
contends that, in that case, the
Environmental Protection Agency (EPA)
was not required to conduct an RFA
analysis because whether the small
entities at issue would be burdened by
the EPA’s action depended on the
intermediate, discretionary action of the
States. Under Order No. 719, however,
TAPS asserts that the RTOs and ISOs
have no such discretion to mitigate the
impact of the Final Rule’s
requirements.45 TAPS further contends
that American Trucking Associations
does not relieve the Commission of its
obligations under the RFA. Therefore, it
suggests that the Commission modify
the ARC requirement as stated above, to
ensure that any relevant electric retail
regulatory authority that wishes to allow
third-party demand response
aggregation could do so, without unduly
42 Joint
Petitioners at 23.
at 26–27.
44 American Trucking Ass’ns v. EPA, 175 F.3d
1027, 1044 (DC Cir. 1999), aff’d in part and rev’d
in part sub nom. Whitman v. American Trucking
Ass’ns, 531 U.S. 457 (2001).
45 TAPS at 28. TAPS states that the Final Rule
‘‘requires [load-serving entities] to either: (1) Invest
in the legislative and/or regulatory procedures
necessary to obtain an explicit ‘out’ and enforce it;
* * * or (2) undertake the implementation burdens
necessary to accommodate ARCs and retail
customers directly bidding retail demand response
into wholesale markets.’’ Id.
43 TAPS
E:\FR\FM\29JYR2.SGM
29JYR2
Federal Register / Vol. 74, No. 144 / Wednesday, July 29, 2009 / Rules and Regulations
burdening hundreds of municipal
entities.46
30. Joint Petitioners argue that the
Commission erred in arbitrarily and
capriciously refusing to consider
APPA’s compromise proposal regarding
third-party aggregation.47 For entities
below the RFA size requirement for
small utilities, the RTO or ISO would be
required to assume that ARC aggregation
is not permitted unless the relevant
electric retail regulatory authority of
such public power system informed the
RTO or ISO that it has elected to allow
such aggregation. Joint Petitioners note
that APPA argued in its NOPR
comments that this size-differentiated
regime would appropriately balance the
Commission’s interest in permitting
demand-side participation in organized
wholesale markets without the undue
burden that the Final Rule places on
small power systems. Joint Petitioners
argue that Order No. 719 noted, but did
not address, APPA’s compromise
proposal.48
31. Similarly, TAPS asserts that, at a
minimum, any affirmative regulatory
action requirement should be restricted
to systems that are larger than the RFA
threshold of 4 million MWh. An
alternative threshold, according to
TAPS, would be ‘‘those municipals with
retail sales of more than 500 million
kWh, as used in the PURPA.’’ 49 TAPS
contends that limiting the application of
the Final Rule’s requirements in this
manner would minimize the burden on
small systems associated with either
implementation of the Final Rule or
compliance with its express prohibition
requirement, consistent with the Final
Rule’s RFA certification.
iii. Effect on Existing Demand Response
Programs and on Rates, Metering, and
Billing Protocols
32. TAPS argues on rehearing that the
Commission failed to: (1) Adequately
address the Final Rule’s impact on
existing demand response programs;
46 Id.
at 29.
Petitioners at 27. In its NOPR comments,
APPA suggested an alternative approach of
differentiating public power systems by their size.
Under this alternative, the relevant electric retail
regulatory authorities governing public power
systems that are located in the RTO or ISO regions
and larger than the RFA size requirement (i.e., 4
million MWh or more in total output in one year)
would have to consider the issue of third-party
ARCs and aggregation of their retail customers, if
they had not already done so. They would have the
affirmative requirement to inform their RTO or ISO
whether their local election was not to permit the
aggregation by ARCs on their public power systems,
or permit it only under enumerated conditions in
order to preclude third-party bidding of their
consumers’ loads. APPA NOPR Comments at 47–48.
48 Joint Petitioners at 28–29.
49 TAPS at 30.
mstockstill on DSKH9S0YB1PROD with RULES2
47 Joint
VerDate Nov<24>2008
18:36 Jul 28, 2009
Jkt 217001
and (2) provide sufficient evidence to
justify the disruptions to wholesale and
retail service that will be created by
authorizing retail customers to sell their
demand response in wholesale markets.
33. According to TAPS, it requested
in its NOPR comments that the
Commission take steps not to
undermine the existing tariff and
contractual arrangements between loadserving entities and their customers for
demand response programs.50 Yet,
TAPS asserts, the Commission imposed
new requirements without first
independently assessing the Final
Rule’s impact on existing load-servingentity-administered demand response
programs. It asks the Commission to
clarify that the Final Rule’s ARC
requirement would not undermine or
require any changes to existing
aggregation programs that already
function well.51
34. According to TAPS, load-serving
entity based programs provide
significant value to all of their
customers because load-serving entities
can integrate their demand response
programs into their power supply
resource planning. This allows
interruptions to be predictable and
avoids the need to carry planning
reserve for interruptible load. TAPS
adds that customers can enjoy the
protection of load-serving entity power
supply planning and aggregation and
average cost rates when they do not
want to lower their consumption while
wholesale prices are high.
35. TAPS argues that the
Commission’s attempt to direct demand
response into the RTO’s or ISO’s
wholesale energy and ancillary services
markets will cause load-serving entities
to lose the planning benefits that a loadserving-entity-administered demand
response program would normally
provide. The load-serving entity would
need to include in its planning for firm
power supply the full loads of its retail
customers who sell into wholesale
markets or contract with ARCs, as well
as carry full planning reserves to meet
that load. Thus, TAPS asserts, the value
to the load-serving entity and its other
customers of avoiding peak block
generation investments and additional
reserves would be lost.52
36. Similarly, Joint Petitioners note
that many public power systems and
cooperatives have effectively acted as
ARCs for their retail customers. This
benefits customers because these notfor-profit entities pass on any savings
50 Id.
at 14 (citing TAPS NOPR Comments at 13–
17).
PO 00000
51 Id.
at 14–15.
from demand response measures to their
customers in the form of lower rates.
Joint Petitioners conclude that ARCs’
activities would undercut the demand
response regimes their public power
systems and cooperatives already have
in place or are developing by cherrypicking the demand response potential
of specific retail customers, and
reducing the savings to the customers of
the public power system accruing from
such programs.53 Also, they contend
that allowing ARCs to selectively choose
load-serving entity demand response
resources would also deprive those
load-serving entities of important
resources used to keep rates down for
all consumers. Load-serving entities
could no longer control individual
customers’ loads and engage in risk and
portfolio management on behalf of their
customers.54
37. TAPS further argues that, by
authorizing retail customers to sell their
non-consumption at high spot prices,
the Final Rule changes the financial
calculation for retail customers
considering demand response. TAPS
claims that this reduces load-serving
entities’ or customers’ incentives to
make the capital investments necessary
to achieve significant, permanent
reductions in electricity usage, in favor
of short-term, peak-hour reductions that
garner premium payments from ARCs
and the wholesale market.55 TAPS
argues that the load-serving entity’s loss
of control over its retail customers’
demand response could impair the loadserving entity’s ability to plan for its
load and harness that demand response
to reduce the costs of serving all of its
customers.
38. Also, TAPS asserts that permitting
direct demand response participation in
wholesale markets and aggregation by
third-party ARCs will significantly
affect billing, metering, and settlement
for the municipal system at both the
wholesale and retail levels. Specifically,
it contends that any system
implemented by RTOs and ISOs to
prevent double-counting could require
major modifications to both RTO and
ISO metering and settlement protocols
and load-serving entities’ metering and
billing protocols.56 For example, TAPS
states that municipals that allow
individual retail customers and thirdparty ARCs to sell demand response
into wholesale markets may be subject
to phantom energy charges,57 based on
53 Joint
Petitioners at 14–15.
at 15.
55 TAPS at 17.
56 Id. at 18.
57 TAPS provides the following example to
explain ‘‘phantom energy’’:
54 Id.
52 Id.
Frm 00007
37781
Continued
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
E:\FR\FM\29JYR2.SGM
29JYR2
37782
Federal Register / Vol. 74, No. 144 / Wednesday, July 29, 2009 / Rules and Regulations
mstockstill on DSKH9S0YB1PROD with RULES2
the amount of energy that those retail
demand responders would otherwise
have consumed. Consequently, this
could result in deviation charges for
load-serving entities for failure to
accurately schedule their load. TAPS
argues that, if ARC-aggregated load
causes an unexpected drop in a loadserving entity’s load, the load-serving
entity will be subject to uplift charges if
its real-time load is below its day-ahead
load.58 Similarly, it adds that a decrease
or an increase in a load-serving entity’s
load, triggered by unexpected, marketprice driven demand response, could
impose over- and under-scheduling
charges on a load-serving entity under
the SPP’s tariff.59
39. Arguing that demand response
participation in wholesale markets,
either directly or by third-party ARCs,
will affect the scheduling and resource
planning of the load-serving entities that
serve the retail customers providing
demand response, TAPS concludes that
load-serving entities will need to
develop a system for allocating the cost
of phantom energy. TAPS believes that
load-serving entities should assign those
charges only to retail customers whose
decision to sell their demand response
into the wholesale market caused the
load-serving entity to incur those costs.
Accordingly, TAPS requests that the
Final Rule should be modified to direct
RTOs and ISOs to provide detailed
information, in real time, to affected
load-serving entities on: (1) The identity
of all individual retail customer load
involved (even if aggregated by an ARC);
and (2) the amount of such demand
response for each billing interval.60
40. TAPS believes that, in total, the
costs of accommodating wholesale
demand response bids by selected retail
customers outweigh the benefits. It
asserts that the implementation of the
Final Rule to accommodate wholesale
demand response bids by retail
customers will require RTOs and ISOs
and load-serving entities to expend
resources for uncertain benefits. For
[I]f a [transmission-dependent entity] with 100
MW of metered load in a given hour has a retail
customer that has sold 5 MW of demand response
energy into the RTO’s energy imbalance market in
that same hour, then to avoid double-counting the
demand response that is already reflected in the
[load-serving entity’s] metered load, the RTO would
charge the [load-serving entity] for 105 MWh of
energy—i.e. as if the 5 MWh of demand response
energy had been purchased by the [load-serving
entity], delivered to the retail customer, and then
re-sold. Id. at 19–20.
58 Id. at 22. TAPS notes that such a deviation
charge may not apply during an emergency, as
provided elsewhere in Order No. 719.
59 Id. (citing Southwest Power Pool, FERC Electric
Tariff, Fifth Revised Volume No. 1, Attachment AE,
sections 5.3 and 5.4).
60 Id.
VerDate Nov<24>2008
18:36 Jul 28, 2009
Jkt 217001
example, TAPS states that RTOs and
ISOs will incur significant costs to
design brand-new systems to
accommodate, track, and verify demand
response. Therefore, it asks that the
Commission require RTOs and ISOs to
evaluate the efficacy of ARC-based
demand response programs, especially
given the adverse impacts on loadserving-entity-administered demand
response programs, and to implement
them only if that evaluation
demonstrates that the benefits outweigh
the costs.61
b. Commission Determination
41. In the Final Rule, the Commission
adopted the NOPR proposal to require
RTOs and ISOs to amend their market
rules as necessary to permit an ARC to
bid demand response on behalf of retail
customers directly into the RTO’s or
ISO’s organized markets, unless the
laws or regulations of the relevant
electric retail regulatory authority do
not permit a retail customer to
participate. The Commission reasoned
that such an action would reduce a
barrier to demand response
participation in the organized markets
subject to Commission jurisdiction.62 As
discussed below, we affirm this broad
finding, but deny in part and grant in
part requests for rehearing on this issue.
i. Commission Jurisdiction
42. Although the rehearing requests
present the issue of Commission
jurisdiction from various points of view
and with emphasis on various groups of
market participants or activities (and we
will answer these arguments in turn),
they all include the same basic issue:
whether the Commission has
jurisdiction to make rules requiring the
RTOs and ISOs to accept demand
response bids.
43. Section 201(b) of the FPA confers
jurisdiction on the Commission over the
transmission of electric energy in
interstate commerce, and sales of
electric energy at wholesale in interstate
commerce.63 Sections 205 and 206 of
the FPA confer upon the Commission
the responsibility to ensure that rates
and charges for transmission and
wholesale power sales by public
utilities, including any rule, regulation,
practice or contract affecting them, are
just and reasonable and not unduly
discriminatory or preferential.64 While
at 22–23.
No. 719, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,281 at
P 594; NOPR, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 32,628 at P 83.
63 16 U.S.C. 824(b).
64 Section 205(a) of the FPA charges the
Commission with ensuring that rates and charges
for jurisdictional sales by public utilities and ‘‘all
rules and regulations affecting or pertaining to such
PO 00000
61 Id.
62 Order
Frm 00008
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
FPA sections 201(f) and 201(b)(2) make
clear that the Commission’s authorities
under Part II of the FPA do not apply
to governmental entities and certain
electric cooperatives, except as
specifically provided, the Commission’s
regulation of the organized markets
operated by RTOs and ISOs (which are
public utilities) nevertheless affects
governmental and cooperative entities
that participate in those markets.
44. In exercising its FPA section 206
authority to regulate public utility
wholesale sales, the Commission
concluded that well-functioning
competitive wholesale electric markets
should reflect current supply and
demand conditions, and that wholesale
markets work best when demand can
respond to the wholesale price. Thus,
the Commission began this proceeding
with the goal of eliminating those
barriers to demand response
participation in the organized markets,
and to ensure comparable treatment of
all resources in these markets.65 The
Final Rule’s ARC requirement is one
element of the Commission’s effort to
achieve this goal.
45. Courts have recognized that the
Commission has broad authority under
the FPA to identify practices that
‘‘affect’’ public utility wholesale rates
under the FPA.66 For instance, most
recently, the DC Circuit held that it was
within the Commission’s jurisdiction to
review ISO New England’s annual
calculation of the minimum amount of
wholesale electric capacity that must be
available to assure reliable service in the
New England region.67 The court stated
that ‘‘even if all the [Installed Capacity
Requirement] did was help to find the
right price, it would still amount to a
‘practice * * * affecting rates’ ’’ for
purposes of Commission authority.68
rates or charges’’ are just and reasonable. Id.
824d(a). Section 206(a) gives the Commission
authority over rate and charges by public utilities
for jurisdictional sales as well as ‘‘any rule,
regulation, practice or contract affecting such rates
and charges’’ to make sure that they are just and
reasonable and not unduly discriminatory or
preferential. Id. 824e(a).
65 In Order No. 890, the Commission found that
sales of ancillary services by ‘‘load services. * * *
should be permitted where appropriate on a
comparable basis to service provided by generation
resources.’’ Order No. 890, FERC Stats. & Regs.
¶ 31,241 (2007).
66 See, e.g., City of Cleveland v. FERC, 773 F.2d
1368, 1376 (D.C. Cir. 1985) (‘‘[T]here is an
infinitude of practices affecting rates and service.
* * * It is obviously left to the Commission, within
broad bounds of discretion, to give concrete
application to this amorphous directive.’’).
67 Connecticut Dep’t of Public Util. Control v.
FERC, No. 07–1375, slip op. at 14–15 (D.C. Cir. June
23, 2009).
68 Id. at 15. The court further stated that ‘‘[w]here
capacity decisions about an interconnected bulk
power system affect [Commission]-jurisdictional
E:\FR\FM\29JYR2.SGM
29JYR2
Federal Register / Vol. 74, No. 144 / Wednesday, July 29, 2009 / Rules and Regulations
mstockstill on DSKH9S0YB1PROD with RULES2
46. The Commission has found on
several occasions that demand response
affects wholesale markets, rates, and
practices and, therefore, issued orders
on various aspects of electric demand
response in organized markets. Some of
these orders approved various types of
demand response programs, including
programs to allow demand response to
be used as a capacity resource 69 and as
a resource during system emergencies,70
to allow wholesale buyers and
qualifying large retail buyers to bid
demand response directly into the dayahead and real-time energy markets and
certain ancillary services markets,
particularly as a provider of operating
reserves, as well as programs to accept
bids from ARCs.71
47. Demand response affects public
utility wholesale rates because
decreasing demand will tend to result in
lower prices and less price volatility.72
The Commission has noted that demand
response has both a direct and an
indirect effect on wholesale prices. The
direct effect occurs when demand
response is bid directly into the
wholesale market: lower demand means
a lower wholesale price. Demand
response at the retail level affects the
wholesale market indirectly because it
reduces a load-serving entity’s need to
purchase power from the wholesale
market.73 Demand response tends to
flatten an area’s load profile, which in
turn may reduce the need to construct
and use more costly resources during
periods of high demand; the overall
effect is to lower the average cost of
producing energy.74 Demand response
transmission rates for that system * * * they come
within the Commission’s authority,’’ adding that
‘‘there is nothing special about capacity decisions
that places them beyond the Commission’s
jurisdiction’’. Id. at 14–15.
69 See, e.g., PJM Interconnection, LLC, 117 FERC
¶ 61,331 (2006); Devon Power L.L.C., 115 FERC ¶
61,340, order on reh’g, 117 FERC ¶ 61,133 (2006).
70 See, e.g., New York Indep. Sys. Operator, Inc.,
95 FERC ¶ 61,136 (2001); NSTAR Services Co. v.
New England Power Pool, 95 FERC ¶ 61,250 (2001);
New England Power Pool and ISO New England,
Inc., 100 FERC ¶ 61,287, order on reh’g, 101 FERC
¶ 61,344 (2002), order on reh’g, 103 FERC ¶ 61,304,
order on reh’g, 105 FERC ¶ 61,211 (2003); PJM
Interconnection, LLC, 99 FERC ¶ 61,139 (2002).
71 See, e.g., New York Indep. Sys. Operator, Inc.,
95 FERC ¶ 61,223 (2001); New England Power Pool
and ISO New England, Inc., 100 FERC ¶ 61,287,
order on reh’g, 101 FERC ¶ 61,344 (2002), order on
reh’g, 103 FERC ¶ 61,304, order on reh’g, 105 FERC
¶ 61,211 (2003); PJM Interconnection, LLC, 99 FERC
¶ 61,227 (2002).
72 ANOPR, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 32,617 at P 37.
73 NOPR, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 32,628 at P 29.
74 Id. P 30. Increasing the presence of demand
response also provides market participants with
better information about where they should and
should not construct upgrades. ‘‘In current market
contexts, constructing new generation facilities in
response to a higher [installed capacity
requirement] may even feel like an imperative. But
VerDate Nov<24>2008
18:36 Jul 28, 2009
Jkt 217001
can help reduce generator market
power: the more demand response is
able to reduce peak prices, the more
downward pressure it places on
generator bidding strategies by
increasing the risk to a supplier that it
will not be dispatched if it bids a price
that is too high.75 Moreover, demand
response enhances system reliability.76
Thus, because demand response directly
affects wholesale rates, reducing barriers
to demand response in the organized
wholesale markets helps the
Commission to fulfill its responsibility,
under sections 205 and 206 of the FPA,
for ensuring that those rates are just and
reasonable.77
48. While the Commission, in
regulating public utility wholesale sales
under the FPA, may act on demand
response participation in the organized
markets, we emphasize that this
proceeding is a very narrowly-focused
rule with respect to demand response
resources. It directs an RTO or ISO that
operates an organized wholesale electric
market—a market subject to the
Commission’s exclusive jurisdiction—to
reduce certain barriers to demand
petitioners have posited no source for that feeling
other than internalization of the true costs of the
alternatives, which is not only a requirement for
efficient market outcomes, but, again, something the
Commission may concededly pursue.’’ Connecticut
Dep’t of Public Util. Control v. FERC, No. 07–1375,
slip op. at 11 (D.C. Cir. June 23, 2009).
75 NOPR, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 32,628 at P 31.
76 For example, ‘‘[b]y reducing electricity demand
at critical times (e.g., when a generator or a
transmission line unexpectedly fails), demand
response that is dispatched by the system operator
on short notice can help return electric system (or
localized) reserves to pre-contingency levels.’’
Federal Energy Regulatory Commission,
Assessment of Demand Response and Advanced
Metering: Staff Report, Docket No. AD06–2–000, at
11 (Aug. 2006) (2006 FERC Staff Demand Response
Assessment); see also Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission, Assessment of Demand Response and
Advanced Metering: Staff Report, at 50–53 (Dec.
2008) (describing the use of demand response
during system emergencies in 2007 to ensure
system reliability).
77 Where a provision or term directly affects a
wholesale rate, it is within the Commission’s
jurisdiction. See, e.g., Connecticut Dep’t of Public
Util. Control v. FERC, No. 07–1375, slip op. at 10
(D.C. Cir. June 23, 2009) (finding that the
Commission has jurisdiction to directly or
indirectly establish prices for capacity even for the
purposes of incentivizing construction of new
generation facilities); Mississippi Industries v.
FERC, 808 F.2d 1525 (D.C. Cir. 1987), vacated in
part on other grounds, 822 F.2d 1103 (D.C. Cir.
1987) (holding that the Commission had
jurisdiction over the allocation of a nuclear plant’s
capacity and costs because it ‘‘directly affects costs
and, consequently, wholesale rates.’’);
Municipalities of Groton v. FERC, 587 F.2d 1296,
(D.C. Cir. 1978); Cal. Indep. Sys. Operator Corp.,
119 FERC ¶ 61,076, at P 540–56 (2007) (finding that
maintaining adequate resources falls within
Commission jurisdiction because it has a direct and
significant effect on wholesale rates and services);
ISO New England, Inc., 119 FERC ¶ 61,161, at P 18–
30 (2007) (same).
PO 00000
Frm 00009
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
37783
response participation in that market.78
We anticipate that reducing barriers to
demand response participation in
wholesale markets also may have
beneficial effects as described above,
including greater price stability and
better information for market
participants as to where they need to
make grid improvements.
49. Several requests for rehearing
argue that the Final Rule exceeds this
narrow scope, and violates the
separation of Federal and State
jurisdiction, by requiring load-serving
entities, including public power systems
and cooperative utilities, to take
affirmative action to consider the issue
of retail aggregation by ARCs. However,
our Final Rule did not challenge the role
of States and others to decide the
eligibility of retail customers to provide
demand response and, as explained
below, we are taking additional steps to
address the burden allegedly imposed
by our Final Rule on smaller entities.
50. Some rehearing requests,
including those from TAPS and Joint
Petitioners, ask us to assume that an
ARC may not participate in RTO or ISO
markets if the relevant State or local
laws and regulations are unstated or do
not clearly allow ARCs to bid into
wholesale markets. We will grant
rehearing only to the extent consistent
with the compromise proposal by APPA
and TAPS based on the RFA threshold
of 4 million MWh as modified below.
The RTO or ISO should not be in the
position of having to interpret when the
laws or regulations of a relevant electric
retail regulatory authority are unclear.
While we leave it to the relevant retail
authority to decide the eligibility of
retail customers, their decision or policy
should be clear and explicit so that the
RTO or ISO is not tasked with
interpreting ambiguities.
51. However, as discussed below, we
agree with APPA and TAPS that it is
reasonable to take a different approach
here with small utilities.79 The
Commission has previously
distinguished small utilities using a 4
78 Order No. 719, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,281 at
P 3; NOPR, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 32,628 at P 282.
79 The RFA definition of ‘‘small entity’’ refers to
the definition provided in the Small Business Act,
which defines a ‘‘small business concern’’ as a
business that is independently owned and operated
and that is not dominant in its field of operation.
See 5 U.S.C. 601(3), citing to Section 3 of the Small
Business Act, 15 U.S.C. 632. The Small Business
Size Standards component of the North American
Industry Classification system defines a small
utility as one that, including its affiliates is
primarily engaged in the generation, transmission,
or distribution of electric energy for sale, and whose
total electric output for the preceding fiscal year did
not exceed 4 million MWh. 13 CFR 121.202 (Sector
22, Utilities, North American Industry
Classification System (NAICS)) (2004).
E:\FR\FM\29JYR2.SGM
29JYR2
37784
Federal Register / Vol. 74, No. 144 / Wednesday, July 29, 2009 / Rules and Regulations
mstockstill on DSKH9S0YB1PROD with RULES2
million MWh cutoff for purposes of
granting waivers from Order No. 889’s 80
standards of conduct for transmission
providers 81 or determining whether a
specific cooperative should be
considered a non-public utility outside
the scope of a refund obligation
involving the California energy crisis.82
Similarly, Congress used the 4 million
MWh cutoff in EPAct 2005 when
amending exclusions in section 201(f) of
the FPA to include small electric
cooperatives.83 Congress also used this
same cutoff to exempt small utilities
from compliance with any rules or
orders imposed under section 211A of
the FPA, involving open access by
unregulated transmitting utilities.84 We
believe the same considerations
underlying those actions by Congress
and the Commission apply here. Thus,
we will grant rehearing and adopt
herein APPA’s and TAPS’s alternative
proposal, with modifications. We direct
RTOs and ISOs to amend their market
rules as necessary to accept bids from
ARCs that aggregate the demand
response of: (1) The customers of
utilities that distributed more than 4
million MWh in the previous fiscal year,
and (2) the customers of utilities that
distributed 4 million MWh or less in the
previous fiscal year, where the relevant
electric retail regulatory authority
permits such customers’ demand
response to be bid into organized
markets by an ARC. RTOs and ISOs may
not accept bids from ARCs that
aggregate the demand response of: (1)
The customers of utilities that
distributed more than 4 million MWh in
the previous fiscal year, where the
relevant electric retail regulatory
authority prohibits such customers’
demand response to be bid into
organized markets by an ARC, or (2) the
customers of utilities that distributed 4
million MWh or less in the previous
fiscal year, unless the relevant electric
retail regulatory authority permits such
customers’ demand response to be bid
into organized markets by an ARC.85
80 Open Access Same-Time Information System
and Standards of Conduct, Order No. 889, FERC
Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,035, clarified, 77 FERC ¶ 61,253
(1996), order on reh’g, Order No. 889–A, FERC
Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,049, reh’g denied, Order No.
889–B, 81 FERC ¶ 61,253 (1997), aff’d in relevant
part sub nom. Transmission Access Policy Study
Group v. FERC, 225 F.3d 667 (D.C. Cir. 2006).
81 See Wolverine Power Supply Coop., 127 FERC
¶ 61,159, at P 15 (2009).
82 See San Diego Gas & Elec. Co. v. Sellers of
Energy and Ancillary Services in Markets Operated
by the CAISO, 125 FERC ¶ 61,297, at P 24 (2008).
83 16 U.S.C. 824(f).
84 16 U.S.C. 824j–l(c)(1).
85 In the Final Rule, the Commission allowed
RTOs and ISOs to specify certain requirements for
an ARC’s bids, including certification that
participation is not precluded by the relevant
VerDate Nov<24>2008
20:07 Jul 28, 2009
Jkt 217001
52. Petitioners argue that the
Commission lacks jurisdiction over
demand response because a retail
customer’s decision to reduce energy
consumption does not fall within the
Commission’s authority under section
201 of the FPA. They assert that a
reduction in consumption of energy
does not constitute a wholesale sale or
transmission of electric energy in
interstate commerce. Petitioners miss
the point. An RTO’s or ISO’s market
rules are subject to our exclusive
jurisdiction. These rules cover market
bids from generators and from providers
of demand response, which directly
affect wholesale prices as discussed
above. Accordingly, the Commission
has found that it has jurisdiction to
regulate the market rules under which
an RTO or ISO accepts a demand
response bid into a wholesale market.
53. The Commission, in acting within
its FPA jurisdiction, is also furthering
Congressional policy to encourage
demand response programs under
EPAct 2005:
It is the policy of the United States that
time-based pricing and other forms of
demand response, whereby electricity
customers are provided with electricity price
signals and the ability to benefit by
responding to them, shall be encouraged, the
deployment of such technology and devices
that enable electricity customers to
participate in such pricing and demand
response systems shall be facilitated, and
unnecessary barriers to demand response
participation in energy, capacity and
ancillary service markets shall be
eliminated.86
54. We recognize that demand
response is a complex matter that is
subject to the confluence of State and
Federal jurisdiction. The Final Rule’s
intent and effect are neither to
encourage or require actions that would
violate State laws or regulations nor to
classify retail customers and their
representatives as wholesale customers,
as Ohio PUC asserts. The Final Rule also
does not make findings about retail
customers’ eligibility, under State or
local laws, to bid demand response into
the organized markets, either
independently or through an ARC. The
Commission also does not intend to
make findings as to whether ARCs may
do business under State or local laws, or
whether ARCs’ contracts with their
retail customers are subject to State and
local law. Nothing in the Final Rule
authorizes a retail customer to violate
existing State laws or regulations or
contract rights. In that regard, we leave
it to the appropriate State or local
electric retail regulatory authority. Order No. 719,
FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,281 at P 158g.
86 EPAct 2005, section 1252(f) (emphasis added).
PO 00000
Frm 00010
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
authorities to set and enforce their own
requirements.
55. Finally, with regard to AEP’s
request for clarification, we note that
this proceeding is a very narrowlyfocused rule, as discussed above. The
clarification that AEP is seeking
involves State laws and regulations, and
how they are interpreted in relation to
the policies contained in this
proceeding. It is not within the scope of
this rulemaking to interpret individual
State laws and regulations.
ii. Burden on Small Entities and
Regulatory Flexibility Analysis
56. In regard to arguments concerning
the burden of this rule on small entities
and the need for RFA analysis, we
reiterate that the Final Rule does not
require a relevant electric retail
regulatory authority to make any
showing or to take any action in
compliance with the Final Rule.87 The
NOPR specifically stated that those
entities directly affected by this
proceeding are the six RTOs and ISOs,
namely, CAISO, NYISO, PJM, SPP,
Midwest ISO, and ISO New England.88
The Final Rule adopted this approach
and established that its requirements,
including the ARC requirement, apply
only to RTOs and ISOs.89
57. TAPS and Joint Petitioners
contend that the Commission’s
requirement that RTOs and ISOs accept
bids from ARCs makes it imperative for
relevant electric retail regulatory
authorities to decide whether ARCs
within their jurisdiction may offer
demand response into wholesale
markets. TAPS and Joint Petitioners
argue that it would be a major
undertaking for a retail regulator to
clarify for an RTO or ISO whether an
ARC may aggregate the demand
response of retail customers within the
service territories of the load-serving
entities it regulates. However, these
entities have not provided any new
arguments on rehearing, and we
continue to find that the Final Rule does
not require retail regulators to take any
action whatsoever. The Final Rule
indicated only that the RTO and ISO
must accept bids from an ARC unless
the laws or regulations of the relevant
electric retail regulatory authority do
not permit the ARC to bid. It did not
require that retail regulators consider
this issue or make any representation,
nor did it require the RTO or ISO to
impose on retail regulators the task of
87 Order No. 719, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,281 at
P 155.
88 NOPR, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 32,628 at P 291.
89 Order No. 719, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,281 at
P 155, 602.
E:\FR\FM\29JYR2.SGM
29JYR2
mstockstill on DSKH9S0YB1PROD with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 74, No. 144 / Wednesday, July 29, 2009 / Rules and Regulations
communicating this lack of permission
at all, much less through a complex or
burdensome procedure.
58. In its NOPR comments, APPA
proposed an alternative approach,
which Joint Petitioners and TAPS
support on rehearing. APPA suggested
that the retail regulators of public power
systems that have output of more than
4 million MWh in one year would need
to notify their RTOs or ISOs if their
local election was to prohibit ARCs from
aggregating retail customers. In the case
of public power systems that do not
meet this size requirement, however, the
presumption would be reversed: the
RTO or ISO would be required to
assume that aggregation was not
permitted unless the retail regulator
instructed it to do otherwise.
59. In response to those comments,
we reiterate that the Commission does
not intend to impose any affirmative
obligation to act on relevant electric
retail regulatory authorities. We will,
however, grant rehearing in part and
adopt a modified version of APPA’s
proposal. As indicated above, the
Commission believes that using a 4
million MWh cutoff for purposes of
distinguishing small utilities is
appropriate.90
60. Therefore, we direct RTOs and
ISOs to amend their market rules as
necessary to accept bids from ARCs that
aggregate the demand response of: (1)
The customers of utilities that
distributed more than 4 million MWh in
the previous fiscal year, and (2) the
customers of utilities that distributed 4
million MWh or less in the previous
fiscal year, where the relevant electric
retail regulatory authority permits such
customers’ demand response to be bid
into organized markets by an ARC.
RTOs and ISOs may not accept bids
from ARCs that aggregate the demand
response of: (1) The customers of
utilities that distributed more than 4
million MWh in the previous fiscal year,
where the relevant electric retail
regulatory authority prohibits such
customers’ demand response to be bid
into organized markets by an ARC, or (2)
the customers of utilities that
distributed 4 million MWh or less in the
previous fiscal year, unless the relevant
electric retail regulatory authority
permits such customers’ demand
response to be bid into organized
markets by an ARC. Our adoption of a
modified version of APPA’s alternative
proposal provides that relevant electric
retail regulatory authorities of small
utilities meeting the above-noted criteria
need not consider this issue except to
permit ARCs to aggregate the demand
90 See
discussion supra P 51.
VerDate Nov<24>2008
18:36 Jul 28, 2009
Jkt 217001
response of retail customers of such
small utilities.
61. With regard to the arguments that
the Commission erred by failing to do
an RFA analysis, we note that if an
agency certifies that the rule will not
have a significant economic impact on
a substantial number of small entities,
as we have done in the Final Rule, it is
not required to conduct an RFA
analysis.91 RFA does not require an
agency to assess the impact of a rule on
all small entities that may be affected by
a rule, only those entities that would be
directly regulated by the rule.92 While
State and local laws and regulations will
determine whether many utilities—large
or small—may be affected by this rule,
the rule directly regulates only RTOs
and ISOs.
62. Further, we reiterate that in
American Trucking Associations, the
court found that because the States, not
EPA, had direct authority to impose
regulations on small entities, EPA’s rule
did not have a direct impact on small
entities. Accordingly, based on its
holding in Mid-Tex, the court held that
EPA is not required to conduct an RFA
analysis.93 We reject TAPS’s premise
that this case is inapplicable to the issue
of whether an RFA analysis is required
for Order No. 719 because RTOs and
ISOs cannot mitigate the burden
allegedly placed on small entities. The
court in American Trucking
Associations did not hold that whether
the small entities at issue would be
burdened by the EPA’s action depended
on the State’s intermediate and
discretionary action. Rather, the court
noted that a State, under its broad
discretion to determine how it
implements EPA’s rule, may choose not
to comply with EPA’s rule altogether.
This would require EPA to adopt an
implementation plan of its own and,
thereby, impose a direct burden on
small entities.94 The court noted that in
such a circumstance, EPA stated that it
will do an RFA analysis. Therefore,
whether RTOs and ISOs are able to
mitigate this burden is not an issue and
does not affect the finding that Order
No. 719 does not directly impact small
U.S.C. 605(b).
Electric Corp., Inc. v. FERC, 773 F.2d
327, 342 (D.C. Cir. 1985) (Mid-Tex) (‘‘Congress did
not intend to require that every agency consider
every indirect effect that any regulation might have
on small businesses in any stratum of the national
economy’’).
93 American Trucking Associations, 175 F.3d at
1044.
94 Id. at 1044 (‘‘Only if a [s]tate does not submit
a [state implementation plan] that complies with
[EPA’s rule], must the EPA adopt an
implementation plan of its own, which would
require the EPA to decide what burdens small
entities should bear’’).
PO 00000
91 16
92 Mid-Tex
Frm 00011
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
37785
entities, as in American Trucking
Associations.
63. As stated earlier, the Final Rule
does not require relevant electric retail
regulatory authorities to take any
specific action. As such, there was no
direct impact on small entities
associated with the draft regulations,
and the Final Rule did not require a
detailed analysis of alternative
proposals that would have allegedly
mitigated such a burden. We also note
that while the requirements in the Final
Rule will have no direct impact on
small entities, we recognize the
concerns raised by APPA and TAPS.
Therefore, as noted above, we grant
rehearing and adopt a modified version
of APPA’s alternative proposal.
64. Each RTO or ISO is required to
submit, within 90 days of the date that
this order on rehearing is published in
the Federal Register, a compliance
filing with the Commission, proposing
amendments to its tariffs or otherwise
demonstrating how its existing tariffs
and market design comply with the
revisions adopted herein.
iii. Effect on Existing Demand Response
Programs and on Rates, Metering, and
Billing Protocols
65. In the Final Rule, we found that
aggregating small retail customers into
larger pools of resources expands the
amount of resources available to the
market, increases competition, helps
reduce prices to consumers, and
enhances reliability.95 Petitioners have
not demonstrated to the contrary. For
example, petitioners have failed to
present evidence that demand response
aggregated by an ARC does not have the
effect of lowering prices for all
customers and maintaining reliability at
a lower cost than would have been the
case if the RTO or ISO had instead
dispatched a resource that submitted a
higher bid.
66. However, petitioners argue that
the ARC requirement’s effect on the
existing demand response program of
load-serving entities is substantial, and
that the Commission failed to
adequately consider such effects and
certain protocol modifications needed to
accommodate the Final Rule’s policy.
We note that petitioners have not
provided clear evidence of such adverse
impacts, but have merely asserted that
they would occur if retail customers are
permitted to participate in wholesale
markets via ARCs. Also, petitioners
have not shown why the issues they
raise cannot be adequately addressed by
each RTO and ISO through the
95 Order No. 719, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,281 at
P 154.
E:\FR\FM\29JYR2.SGM
29JYR2
37786
Federal Register / Vol. 74, No. 144 / Wednesday, July 29, 2009 / Rules and Regulations
mstockstill on DSKH9S0YB1PROD with RULES2
stakeholder process and included as
part of the RTO’s or ISO’s compliance
filing.96 As a result, we find that
petitioners’ arguments are speculative;
they have not persuaded us that the
policy decisions made in the Final Rule
were the result of error. Therefore, we
deny rehearing.
67. TAPS asks us to clarify that the
Final Rule would not undermine or
require any changes to existing retail
aggregation programs. We reiterate that
the Final Rule is designed to eliminate
barriers to demand response
participation in RTO or ISO markets. To
that end, the Final Rule requires an RTO
or ISO to accept bids into its markets
from an ARC, unless the laws or
regulations of the relevant electric retail
regulatory authority for utilities that had
total electric output for the preceding
fiscal year of more than 4 million MWh
do not permit a retail customer to
participate. For smaller systems under
the RFA size requirement, ARCs may
aggregate retail customers only if
affirmatively permitted to do so by the
relevant electric retail regulatory
authority. Each RTO or ISO is required
to work with its stakeholders to propose
methods of implementing this
requirement in its region. The intent of
the Final Rule is not to interfere with,
undermine, or change existing demand
response programs. Nothing in the Final
Rule would require a State or local
regulator to take any action or prevent
them from: (1) Preserving existing
aggregation programs, in whatever
fashion is appropriate for its
jurisdictional area; or (2) authorizing
retail customers, via an ARC, to
participate in wholesale markets.
68. TAPS and Joint Petitioners
emphasize that existing retail
aggregation programs provide
significant benefits that would be
adversely impacted or lost by the Final
Rule’s ARC requirement. This is not the
proper forum to address these issues,
which are for the relevant electric retail
regulatory authority to consider. It is up
to the relevant electric retail regulatory
authorities, if they so choose, to decide
whether existing retail aggregation
programs provide benefits and whether
retail customer participation in
wholesale demand response programs,
96 The Final Rule provided regional flexibility for
each RTO and ISO to work with its stakeholders in
proposing market rules appropriate for its region.
Id. P 155. Interested parties could participate in that
stakeholder process. By filing comments on the
RTO’s or ISO’s subsequent compliance filing,
interested parties had an additional opportunity to
address the Commission directly on any remaining
concerns with the RTO’s or ISO’s implementation
proposal. The Commission will address the merits
of such implementation issues on a case-by-case
basis.
VerDate Nov<24>2008
18:36 Jul 28, 2009
Jkt 217001
individually or through an ARC, would
adversely affect those programs and, if
so, whether and how to permit such
participation. Therefore, TAPS and Joint
Petitioners may raise these issues with
the relevant electric retail regulatory
authority.
69. TAPS also contends that the Final
Rule’s ARC requirement will affect
billing, metering, and settlement
protocols at both the wholesale and
retail level because major system
modifications are needed to address
double counting, phantom energy, and
verification measures. TAPS and others
also express concern that a load-serving
entity may buy too much power if its
retail customer bids in demand response
and the load-serving entity is unaware
of the bid, creating an over-scheduling
penalty for the load-serving entity. We
note that several RTOs and ISOs
currently have demand response
programs where demand response
resources participate either individually
or through an ARC. Some of these RTOs
and ISOs have addressed the type of
concerns raised by TAPS with regard to
double counting, verification
procedures, deviation charges and the
like. We will require each RTO or ISO,
through the stakeholder process, to
develop appropriate mechanisms for
sharing information about demand
response resources to address the
concerns raised by TAPS and others. We
direct each RTO and ISO, through the
stakeholder process, to develop, at a
minimum, a mechanism through which
an affected load-serving entity would be
notified when load served by that entity
is enrolled to participate, either
individually or through an ARC, as a
demand response resource in an RTO or
ISO market and the expected level of
that participation for each enrolled
demand response resource.97 Finally,
we direct each RTO and ISO to submit
a compliance filing no later than 180
days from the date of this order
indicating how it has complied with
these requirements.
70. Therefore, as stated in the Final
Rule, we require each RTO or ISO to
work with its stakeholders, including
load-serving entities and ARCs, to
develop and implement protocols that
will address those issues and allow
ARCs to operate within the organized
market. Those protocols should address
those issues raised by petitioners,
including double-counting, concerns
regarding deviation, underscheduling,
and uplift or other charges that may be
97 TAPS requested, among other things, that we
direct the RTO or ISO to provide certain detailed
information in real-time to affected load-serving
entities. TAPS has failed to demonstrate the need
for such data in real-time.
PO 00000
Frm 00012
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
incurred if real-time load is below that
scheduled in the day-ahead market, as
well as metering, billing, settlement,
information sharing and verification
measures to be submitted in an RTO’s
or ISO’s compliance filing ordered
above.
71. We again reject the argument that
the Commission should require RTOs
and ISOs to evaluate the efficacy of
ARC-based demand response programs
given the costs involved in modifying
systems to accommodate bids by retail
customers and the adverse impact on
load-serving entity administered
programs. As stated above, RTOs and
ISOs, in conjunction with their
stakeholders, including ARCs and loadserving entities, are in the best position
to decide whether to incur the costs of
conducting such an analysis. In
recognition of regional differences, the
Final Rule directed each RTO and ISO
to work with its stakeholders to discuss
and resolve concerns, including
demonstrating net benefits of its
program and to address these issues in
its compliance filing with the
Commission.98
3. Market Rules Governing Price
Formation During Periods of Operating
Reserve Shortage
72. In the Final Rule, the Commission
found that existing RTO and ISO market
rules that do not allow prices to rise
sufficiently during an operating reserve
shortage to allow supply to meet
demand are unjust and unreasonable,
and may be unduly discriminatory.99
The Commission stated that these rules
may not produce prices that accurately
reflect the true value of energy in such
an emergency and, by failing to do so,
may harm reliability, inhibit demand
response, deter new entry of demand
response and generation resources, and
thwart innovation.100
73. The Commission established
reforms to remove barriers to demand
response by requiring RTOs and ISOs to
reform their market rules in such a way
that prices during operating reserve
shortages more accurately reflect the
value of energy during such shortages.
The Final Rule required each RTO or
ISO to reform or demonstrate the
adequacy of its existing market rules to
ensure that the market price for energy
reflects the value of energy during an
operating reserve shortage.101 Each RTO
or ISO may propose in its compliance
filing one of four suggested approaches
98 Order No. 719, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,281 at
P 159.
99 Id. P 192.
100 Id.
101 Id. P 194.
E:\FR\FM\29JYR2.SGM
29JYR2
Federal Register / Vol. 74, No. 144 / Wednesday, July 29, 2009 / Rules and Regulations
to pricing reform during an operating
reserve shortage, or develop its own
alternative approach to achieve the
same objectives.102 The Final Rule also
required each RTO or ISO to support its
compliance filing with adequate factual
support. To that end, the Commission
outlined six criteria it will consider in
reviewing whether the factual record
compiled by the RTO or ISO meets the
requirements of the Final Rule.103 The
Final Rule also allowed an RTO or ISO
to phase in any new pricing rules for a
period of a few years, provided that this
period is not protracted.
a. Requests for Rehearing
mstockstill on DSKH9S0YB1PROD with RULES2
i. Shortage Pricing Proposal
74. Several petitioners requested
rehearing of the Commission’s shortage
pricing requirement on grounds that the
requirement would eliminate price caps
during periods when bidders could
exercise market power; that customers
do not yet have in place the tools to
respond to price; that there is not
sufficient market mitigation in place to
ensure a competitive result; that the
Commission did not provide sufficient
evidence that its shortage pricing
requirement would achieve its stated
goals; or that the Commission ignored
arguments or evidence provided by
NOPR commenters indicating that the
Commission’s proposal may not achieve
the desired results.
75. Joint Petitioners argue that the
Commission failed to substantiate its
finding that existing RTO and ISO
market rules are unjust and
unreasonable because they do not allow
prices to rise sufficiently during
102 The four approaches are: (1) RTOs and ISOs
would increase the energy supply and demand bid
caps above the current levels only during an
emergency; (2) RTOs and ISOs would increase bid
caps above the current level during an emergency
only for demand bids while keeping generation bid
caps in place; (3) RTOs and ISOs would establish
a demand curve for operating reserves, which has
the effect of raising prices in a previously agreedupon way as operating reserves grow short; and (4)
RTOs and ISOs would set the market-clearing price
during an emergency for all supply and demand
response resources dispatched equal to the payment
made to participants in an emergency demand
response program. Id. P 208.
103 The six criteria are: (1) Improve reliability by
reducing demand and increasing supply during
periods of operating reserve shortages; (2) make it
more worthwhile for customers to invest in demand
response technologies; (3) encourage existing
generation and demand resources to continue to be
relied upon during an operating reserve shortage;
(4) encourage entry of new generation and demand
resources; (5) ensure that the principle of
comparability in treatment of and compensation to
all resources is not discarded during periods of
operating reserve shortage; and (6) ensure market
power is mitigated and gaming behavior is deterred
during periods of operating reserve shortages
including, but not limited to, showing how demand
resources discipline bidding behavior to
competitive levels. Id. P 246–47.
VerDate Nov<24>2008
18:36 Jul 28, 2009
Jkt 217001
operating reserve shortages. Joint
Petitioners state that any higher prices
during operating reserve shortages
would reflect market power, not
efficient shortage pricing.104 They state
that given the existing market power
problems in organized markets, raising
price caps can result in prices that are
inefficiently high. Joint Petitioners note
that, in concluding that market power
will be adequately mitigated through the
shortage pricing requirement, the
Commission ignored contrary evidence
from APPA and NRECA.105
76. Similarly, TAPS states that the
Commission must have empirical proof
that existing competition would ensure
that the actual price is just and
reasonable before it permits RTOs and
ISOs to remove price caps during
emergencies. Yet, according to TAPS,
the Final Rule’s shortage pricing
requirement lacks evidence that existing
offer and bid caps actually limit demand
response, that lifting such caps will
attract investment in generation and
demand response sufficient to protect
consumers from market power, and that
consumers will be able to protect
themselves from high prices.106 In light
of contrary evidence, TAPS contends
that the Commission must provide
evidence that consumers will be able to
protect themselves from high prices
through demand response programs. For
instance, TAPS states that existing
evidence indicates that the short-run
demand curve for electricity is highly
inelastic.107
77. SMUD argues that the
Commission’s decision to lift price and
bid caps constitutes an arbitrary and
unexplained departure from its
precedent.108 It states that the
Commission has previously established
that demand response technologies are
insufficiently developed to permit the
relaxation of bid caps109 and the Final
Rule fails to demonstrate how
circumstances are sufficiently different
Petitioners at 32–33.
at 44 (citing NRECA Affidavit at P 20–55).
106 TAPS at 33 (citing TAPS NOPR Comments at
24–27).
107 Id. at 39.
108 For example, SMUD explains that in NYISO,
the Commission imposed a bid cap based on its
finding that the NYISO market lacks demand-side
responsiveness to prices and that it has tight
supplies. Id. at 5. (citing New York Indep. System
Operator, 97 FERC ¶ 61,154, at 61,673 (2001)).
SMUD also adds that the Commission previously
found that price caps are necessary to prevent
opportunistic pricing during periods of capacity
shortages and that bid caps provide a safety net to
contain prices in peak periods when supply is
short. SMUD at 4. (citing ISO New England, Inc.,
97 FERC ¶ 61,090, at 62,469, 61,470–471 (2001)).
109 Id. at 4. (citing Nstar Serv. Co. v. New England
Power Pool, 92 FERC ¶ 61,065, at 62,198–99 (2000)).
PO 00000
104 Joint
105 Id.
Frm 00013
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
37787
to warrant a change in Commission
policy.
78. Joint Petitioners maintain that
allowing real-time market-clearing
prices to exceed price caps during
periods of shortage will increase price
volatility, which in turn may increase
hedging costs.110 Industrial Coalitions
submit that the Commission should
develop metrics for measuring demand
elasticity and for evaluating whether
higher and more volatile prices actually
become a key factor in capital
deployment decisions. In support, they
argue that demand response
infrastructure remains underdeveloped,
and therefore cannot serve as a viable
check on the exercise of market
power.111
79. Pennsylvania PUC asserts that
without real-time demand response, the
Commission’s assumption that shortage
pricing will represent the true value of
supply is false because only supply-side
resources will be able to respond to
prices and such one-sided markets
cannot be protected from the exercise of
market power.112 Joint Petitioners also
argue that the Final Rule wrongly
concluded that demand response itself
will act as a market power mitigation
measure based on a faulty assumption
that end-use customers will be able to
respond to shortage pricing by reducing
their demand.113
80. Similarly, Old Dominion asserts
that the Commission erred in mandating
a shortage pricing requirement, without
first addressing an approach to
eliminate non-price barriers. It contends
that the Commission noted, but did not
address, its NOPR comments that
consumers will face increased prices
without the ability to respond to price
signals. Old Dominion contends that it
is difficult to ascertain whether
legitimate market forces or the exercise
of market power is the cause of
increased prices, and that the solution is
not to mandate removal of price
protections that are necessary for
market-based rates to be just and
reasonable. Old Dominion adds that the
capacity auction structure under PJM’s
Reliability Pricing Model is designed to
capture scarcity rents; that there should
not be double collection through an
aggressive shortage pricing construct;
and that there is an existing construct
that seeks to meet the reliability and
incentive goals of the Final Rule.114
Therefore, it requests that the
Commission take up the issue of
110 Joint
Petitioners at 41.
Coalition at 7–8.
112 Pennsylvania PUC at 5.
113 Joint Petitioners at 48–49.
114 Old Dominion at 4.
111 Industrial
E:\FR\FM\29JYR2.SGM
29JYR2
37788
Federal Register / Vol. 74, No. 144 / Wednesday, July 29, 2009 / Rules and Regulations
whether to mandate shortage pricing
only after it has addressed proposals on
eliminating barriers to demand
response. In the alternative, Old
Dominion renews its request that the
Commission adopt a presumption that
such pricing incentives are not
necessary, and require RTOs and ISOs
that believe otherwise to make a factual
demonstration in support of their
proposal.115
81. Ohio PUC states that the
Commission adopted a proposal to
remove bid caps for generation during
periods of operating reserve shortage,
but should also consider raising bid
caps only for demand bids until market
power concerns are alleviated and the
market for demand response is more
fully developed.116
82. Joint Petitioners note that if the
Commission is serious about including
consumer protections, including
meaningful market power mitigation
mechanisms in RTO and ISO shortage
pricing filings, the Commission should
require evidentiary hearings regarding
the RTO’s and ISO’s shortage pricing
proposals and the sufficiency of their
proposed mitigation mechanisms.117
83. TAPS contends that the
Commission failed to clarify the
definition of operating reserve shortage
and ignored TAPS’s concern that the
definition may be too broad. TAPS also
notes that the preamble to the Final
Rule suggests that the Commission
intended to define an operating reserve
shortage as falling short of meeting the
operating reserve requirements under
the reliability standards approved by the
Commission under FPA section 215,118
yet the regulatory text provides a
definition without referring to these
reliability standards. Therefore, it
suggests that the Commission revise the
definition to restrict shortage pricing to
instances where the RTO or ISO risks
being unable to replenish operating
reserves within the period specified in
applicable reliability standards.119
mstockstill on DSKH9S0YB1PROD with RULES2
ii. Four Shortage Pricing Approaches
and Criteria Requirements
84. Several petitioners requested
rehearing of the Commission’s shortage
pricing approaches on grounds that the
Commission failed to consider evidence
presented by NOPR commenters that
one or more of the approaches will not
115 Id.
at 5–6.
PUC at 7.
117 They note that the Commission never
addressed APPA’s request for full evidentiary
hearings. Id. at 49 (citing APPA NOPR Comments
at 54–55, 62, 64).
118 Order No. 719, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,281
at P 251.
119 TAPS at 54–56.
116 Ohio
VerDate Nov<24>2008
18:36 Jul 28, 2009
Jkt 217001
achieve the desired results; that the
Commission did not adequately
consider alternative approaches or
criteria presented by NOPR
commenters; and that the Commission
needed to provide more direction to
RTOs and ISOs on how to implement its
proposal and to provide evidence of its
expected benefits.
85. TAPS states that the Commission
ignored NOPR comments regarding the
defects of the four shortage pricing
approaches. TAPS argues that the four
approaches are not just and reasonable
because they: (1) Fail to protect
consumers from market power; (2) are
premised on unsupported assumptions
about bidding behavior and consumers;
(3) require the adoption of particular
wholesale market structures that have
not been established in all RTOs and
ISOs; and (4) may encourage gaming.120
86. Joint Petitioners argue that the
Commission acted arbitrarily and
capriciously by failing to consider
evidence from NOPR comments,
including those provided by NRECA,
that the four shortage pricing
approaches will not achieve the
Commission’s stated goals.121 They
assert that the four approaches will: (1)
Fail to protect consumers and lead to
unjust and unreasonable rates; (2)
undermine reliability or preserve
reliability only by unlawfully shifting
rents from consumers to generators; (3)
encourage behavior by generators that
creates emergencies; and (4) not attract
new supply resources to real-time or
long-term markets.122
87. Joint Petitioners and TAPS argue
that the Final Rule failed to discuss the
merits of NRECA’s alternative approach,
which was to allow only demand
response resources to bid prices higher
than the current bid caps during
emergencies. Under this approach, Joint
Petitioners state that demand response
resources would be paid the highest
clearing price bid by demand response
resources; however, generators would
receive the highest capped price bid by
generating resources needed to clear the
market.123 TAPS states that this
approach would have potential benefits
for emergencies, with fewer adverse
consequences than any of the Final
Rule’s four approaches. Therefore, it
asks the Commission to address the
merits of NRECA’s approach and modify
the regulatory text to accommodate this
at 42–45.
Petitioners at 35 (citing Order No. 719,
FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,281 at P 235).
122 Id. at 41.
123 Id. at 49–50 (citing NRECA NOPR Comments
at 29).
PO 00000
120 Id.
121 Joint
Frm 00014
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
approach.124 Joint Petitioners argue that
the Commission acted arbitrarily and
capriciously in failing to consider
NRECA’s detailed arguments and
evidence which they claim show that
the four shortage pricing approaches
will result in unjust and unreasonable
rates and charges, not the beneficial
results that the Final Rule anticipates.
88. Joint Petitioners assert that
generator resources and demand
response resources are not similarly
situated and, therefore, it is not unjust
and unreasonable or unduly
discriminatory under the FPA to
compensate them differently. According
to Joint Petitioners, during generation
scarcity, generators already make all of
their generation resources available to
the market; hence, they can take no
additional actions to balance supply and
demand. However, they assert that
demand response resources are able to
take further action to balance supply
and demand by reducing their
demand.125 Therefore, the
comparability principle does not require
that the same price to be paid to both
generators and demand responders to
bring supply and demand into balance.
89. Joint Petitioners argue that the
Commission failed to address APPA’s
proposal for eight additional criteria
intended to better protect consumers
from the exercise of market power and
unjust and unreasonable rates.126 They
also contend that the Commission failed
to address NRECA’s request that the
Commission require RTOs and ISOs to
quantify the benefits of proposed
changes and to demonstrate that they
exceed the costs, which should include
the expected costs of market power.127
90. Similarly, TAPS asserts that the
Final Rule ignored its NOPR comments
for additional criteria to strengthen the
factual showing required for RTOs and
ISOs in their shortage pricing
compliance filings. TAPS believes that
its proposed criteria would address
market power and provide
accountability.128
124 TAPS states that the Final Rule’s regulatory
text language in section 35.28(g)(1)(iv)(A) would
preclude an RTO or ISO from proposing the NRECA
approach or any other beneficial demand response
program. Thus, it requests the following
modifications:
Commission-approved ISOs and RTOs must
modify their market rules to allow (1) the marketclearing price during periods of operating reserve
shortage to reach a level that rebalances supply and
demand or (2) payments to demand response
resources. In either case, the rules must [so as to]
maintain reliability while providing sufficient
provisions for mitigating market power.
TAPS at 48 (citing TAPS NOPR Comments at 3).
125 Joint Petitioners at 42.
126 Id. at 51–52.
127 Id. at 53.
128 Id. at 49.
E:\FR\FM\29JYR2.SGM
29JYR2
Federal Register / Vol. 74, No. 144 / Wednesday, July 29, 2009 / Rules and Regulations
91. TAPS also seeks rehearing of the
Commission’s rejection of Pacific Gas &
Electric Corporation’s (PG&E) proposed
additional criteria, especially with
regard to the cost effectiveness of the
Final Rule’s shortage pricing
requirements. TAPS argues that the
Commission did not provide a reasoned
basis for rejecting PG&E’s proposed
criteria. It adds that the Commission’s
failure to require any accountability for
the costs imposed by the Final Rule’s
shortage pricing requirements is
contrary to the GAO Report’s
recommendations.129
92. Joint Petitioners request that the
Commission vacate the relevant criteria
and regulations, and undertake a
successor rulemaking with a new record
to develop demand response pricing
policies that meet the statutory
requirements of the FPA.130
b. Commission Determination
93. The requests for rehearing do not
convince us that the policy decisions
made in the Final Rule were the result
of error. We therefore affirm our finding
in the Final Rule that existing RTO and
ISO market rules that do not allow for
prices to rise sufficiently during an
operating reserve shortage to allow
supply to meet demand are unjust,
unreasonable, and may be unduly
discriminatory. The shortage pricing
proposal adopted in the Final Rule is
intended to correct this issue while
providing protection against the
exercise of market power. Therefore, we
deny rehearing on this issue.
mstockstill on DSKH9S0YB1PROD with RULES2
i. Shortage Pricing Proposal
94. Several petitioners state that the
Commission lacked evidence for
establishing shortage pricing
requirements. We disagree. Based on
information gathered from three
technical conferences 131 and comments
in response to the ANOPR and the
NOPR, the Commission found that
today’s RTO and ISO market rules may
not produce rates that accurately reflect
the true value of energy during periods
of operating reserve shortages. The
Commission determined that such
inaccurate prices during an emergency
129 Id. at 53 (citing United States Government
Accountability Office, Report to the Committee on
Homeland Security and Governmental Affairs, U.S.
Senate, Electricity Restructuring: FERC Could Take
Additional Steps to Analyze Regional Transmission
Organizations’ Benefits and Performance (Sept.
2008), available at https://www.gao.gov/new.items/
d08987.pdf) (2008 GAO Report)).
130 Joint Petitioners at 54.
131 The Commission held three technical
conferences in 2007 to gather information and
address issues on competition at the wholesale
level and other related issues. See NOPR, FERC
Stats. & Regs. ¶ 32,628 at P 2.
VerDate Nov<24>2008
18:36 Jul 28, 2009
Jkt 217001
may harm reliability, inhibit demand
response, deter new entry of demand
response and generation resources, and
thwart innovation.132 Therefore, the
Commission concluded that RTO or ISO
market rules that do not allow for prices
to rise sufficiently during an operating
reserve shortage to allow supply to meet
demand are unjust, unreasonable, and
may be unduly discriminatory.133
95. We disagree with the arguments
that the Final Rule’s shortage pricing
requirement will result in the exercise
of market power or lead to increased
price volatility, or that consumers will
not be protected from high prices, or
that it is a departure from Commission
precedent because it removes bid and
price caps that are in place to mitigate
market power. As stated in the Final
Rule, the Commission is not taking any
action to remove bid caps or to remove
market power mitigation in regional
markets. Rather, the Commission is
requiring each RTO and ISO to
demonstrate that its market rules
accurately reflect the value of energy
during reserve shortage periods or to
propose changes in its rules to achieve
this objective. Each of the Commission’s
four proposals maintains bid and price
caps, but would allow price caps to rise
during shortage periods provided that
the RTO or ISO demonstrates that
adequate market power mitigation
provisions are in place. Each RTO or
ISO also is free to propose other pricing
approaches and associated market
power mitigation that meet the purposes
and criteria described in the Final
Rule.134 The RTOs’ and ISOs’
compliance filings are subject to
Commission review and approval. Also,
to guard the consumer against
exploitation by sellers, the Commission
required each RTO and ISO to
adequately address market power issues
in the compliance filing and for MMUs
to provide their views to the
Commission on any proposed
reforms.135
96. With regard to arguments that the
Final Rule provided no evidence that
existing shortage pricing rules are
inhibiting investment in demand
response resources, we note that the
issue is not whether existing market
rules remain workable. As we have
explained many times, one of the
Commission’s goals in this proceeding
is to eliminate barriers to demand
response resources’ participation in
132 Order No. 719, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,281
at P 192; NOPR, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 32,628 at P
107.
133 Order No. 719, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,281
at P 192.
134 Id. P 195.
135 Id. P 235.
PO 00000
Frm 00015
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
37789
organized energy markets. If, as
petitioners foresee, higher shortage
prices result from amending market
rules, those prices could be expected to
attract investment in both demand
response technology and generation by
providing opportunities for a higher
return on investment—and the entry of
demand response over time may lead to
lower prices in the long run. We are
concerned that such investments may
not occur under existing rules because,
as at least one commenter observed in
response to the NOPR ‘‘existing market
rules do not accurately reflect the value
of energy during periods of shortage
and, therefore may deter new entry of
demand response and generation
resources.’’ 136 Also, we do not find that
it is necessary to develop metrics for
measuring demand elasticity or for
evaluating the impact that volatile
prices may have on capital deployment
decisions, as Industrial Coalitions claim.
As noted above, the Commission’s goal
in this proceeding is to eliminate
barriers to demand response
participation in RTO and ISO markets,
and it is reasonable to expect that higher
shortage prices will encourage
investment in additional generation and
demand response resources.
97. In response to TAPS’s statement
that a highly inelastic demand curve
means that consumers cannot protect
themselves from high prices, the
Commission notes first that demand is
not necessarily inelastic when
customers have appropriate notice and
prices,137 and second that even a
relatively small amount of demand
response in a shortage can lower market
prices significantly for all customers.
98. Several petitioners assert that
customers are not able to respond to
prices in real-time and, therefore,
demand response mechanisms must be
in place before changes to mitigation
rules are considered. We agree with
Pennsylvania PUC, Old Dominion,
Industrial Coalitions, and others that
demand response infrastructures remain
underdeveloped for many regions.
Developing mechanisms to allow prices
to reflect the true value of energy during
an emergency should encourage
development of demand response
infrastructure. With improved price
136 Id. P 187 (citing PJM Power Providers NOPR
Comments at 3).
137 For example, a critical peak pricing
experiment in California in 2004 determined that
small residential and commercial customers are
price responsive and will produce significant
demand reductions. Participants in the California
peak pricing experiment reduced demand by 13
percent on average and by as much as 27 percent
when price signals were coupled with automated
controls, such as controllable thermostats. 2006
FERC Staff Demand Response Assessment at 13.
E:\FR\FM\29JYR2.SGM
29JYR2
mstockstill on DSKH9S0YB1PROD with RULES2
37790
Federal Register / Vol. 74, No. 144 / Wednesday, July 29, 2009 / Rules and Regulations
signals, more buyers would find it
worthwhile to invest in technologies
that allow them to respond to prices. As
noted in the Final Rule, full deployment
of advanced meters and complete
participation by all load is not needed
to help cope with operating reserve
shortages. Demand response programs
that currently allow a fraction of the
load to respond can have a significant
positive effect on system reliability and
help reduce prices for all.
99. With regard to Old Dominion’s
request that the Commission address
each RTO’s or ISO’s proposal for
eliminating barriers to demand response
before mandating shortage pricing, and
Joint Coalitions’ concern that existing
demand response cannot check the
exercise of market power, we note that
the Final Rule requires each RTO and
ISO to provide evidence regarding the
ability of demand resources to mitigate
market power and how market power
will be monitored.138 The Commission
will examine the shortage pricing
proposals submitted in each RTO’s and
ISO’s compliance filing and will
approve the proposals only if they meet
the criteria established in the Final
Rule.
100. Finally, with regard to TAPS’s
request for revision of the definition of
operating reserve shortage in the
regulatory text, we decline to revise the
regulatory text because we do not
believe the definition is either
inadequate or inconsistent with the
discussion in the preamble of the Final
Rule. The regulatory text provided a
short general definition of an operating
reserve shortage and the preamble
declined to provide a detailed
specification of when an operating
reserve shortage exists, stating that the
North American Electric Reliability
Corporation already specifies
procedures for determining when a
system operator is out of compliance
with the reliability standard and
therefore when it has an operating
reserve shortage. These standards are
well known to RTOs and ISOs and their
stakeholders.139 Given that the level of
operating reserves required by the
reliability standards depend on the
characteristic of each system and cannot
be correctly reduced to a single number
that applies to every system, the
Commission found that it would be best
not to adopt in these regulations a new
and separate specification of when an
operating reserve shortage exists. The
Commission found that if it were to
duplicate the provisions of the
138 Order No. 719, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,281
at P 196.
139 Id. P 251.
VerDate Nov<24>2008
18:36 Jul 28, 2009
Jkt 217001
reliability standard in this rulemaking,
it would be cumbersome for reliability
organizations to improve their
specifications of when such a shortage
exists without also having to seek a
change in our regulations. Therefore, we
deny rehearing of this request.
101. We reject Joint Petitioners’
request that we require by rule an
evidentiary hearing to determine the
justness and reasonableness of each
RTO’s and ISO’s shortage pricing
proposal. We find that at this stage it is
premature to establish a requirement for
such evidentiary hearings. All
concerned parties have now had an
opportunity to comment on the RTOs’
and ISOs’ compliance filings, and the
Commission will determine on a caseby-case basis whether evidentiary
hearings are warranted. We reject Joint
Petitioners’ request to vacate the
rulemaking provisions on shortage
pricing and institute a new rulemaking.
We find that the Joint Petitioners have
not provided any new arguments or
evidence that would warrant such
action.
ii. Four Shortage Pricing Approaches
and Criteria Requirements
102. Several petitioners find fault
with the four shortage pricing
approaches, stating that they fail to
protect customers from the exercise of
market power and lead to other adverse
consequences. We find that these
petitioners have not raised any new
arguments on rehearing and deny
rehearing on this issue.
103. We emphasize that the Final
Rule did not establish the shortage rates
to be implemented, or even one
particular approach to shortage pricing.
In particular, the Final Rule did not
require the first approach of raising bid
caps, as some petitioners suggest.
Rather, it required RTOs and ISOs to
make a compliance filing, in
consultation with their customers and
other stakeholders, to establish an
approach to shortage pricing during
periods of operating reserve shortage or
to show that their existing rules satisfy
the Final Rule. Further, this compliance
filing must make several of the
demonstrations that petitioners contend
are lacking in the Final Rule, such as
ensuring that market power is mitigated
and gaming behavior is deterred during
periods of operating reserve
shortages.140 Only after such filings
have been submitted will the
Commission determine, case by case for
each RTO or ISO, if the existing or
proposed pricing rules—which could
include, but are not required to include,
PO 00000
140 Id.
P 247.
Frm 00016
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
raising bid caps—are just and
reasonable and sufficient to meet the
stated goals of this proceeding.141 The
Commission provided a menu of
options through the four approaches or
any other approach that the RTO or ISO
deems appropriate. Therefore, an RTO
or ISO and its stakeholders are free to
consider approaches other than the four
approaches in the Final Rule and
propose it to the Commission, provided
it satisfies the requirements in the Final
Rule.
104. With regard to NRECA’s
alternative approach for pricing reform,
we reiterate that the Final Rule did not
mandate any specific approach to
shortage pricing. It presented four
approaches to shortage pricing, but left
the RTOs and ISOs with freedom to
develop the solutions that best suit their
regions.142 RTOs and ISOs may consider
NRECA’s alternative proposal, or others
not presented in the Final Rule, as they
see fit.143 We therefore disagree with
Joint Petitioners’ contention that the
Commission erred in failing to require
NRECA’s proposal and in overlooking
evidence that the four approaches will
result in unreasonable rates and charges.
Such analysis is most appropriately left
to the compliance process, where the
Commission can examine how the
RTO’s or ISO’s chosen approach or
approaches to shortage prices will work
in its region.
105. Joint Petitioners and TAPS argue
that the Final Rule ignored some
proposals for additional criteria aimed
at addressing their concerns, including
market power and accountability. While
the Final Rule did not specifically
address the merits of each additional
criterion proposed, the Commission
considered them in adopting and
revising the six criteria from the
NOPR.144 The Commission found that
many of the suggestions for additional
criteria are already implicitly or
explicitly addressed in the adopted
criteria. For example, the Commission
noted that the criteria already included
an analysis of market power mitigation
and, therefore, did not see the need to
adopt an additional criterion to protect
consumers against market power.145 We
therefore continue to find that the
criteria adopted in the Final Rule are
sufficient to provide a general guideline
for designing a shortage pricing
approach that addresses market power,
accountability, gaming behavior, and
141 Id.
P 235.
No. 719, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,281
at P 194–95.
143 Id. P 195.
144 Order No. 719, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,281
at P 239, 249–50.
145 Id. P 249.
142 Order
E:\FR\FM\29JYR2.SGM
29JYR2
Federal Register / Vol. 74, No. 144 / Wednesday, July 29, 2009 / Rules and Regulations
other issues raised by petitioners.
Therefore, we disagree that the Final
Rule ignored proposals for additional
criteria.
106. Similarly, we see no basis to
reconsider PG&E’s proposed criteria
which were: (1) A demonstration that
any proposed market rule changes are
cost effective; (2) an evaluation that the
operating reserve shortage pricing
mechanism is adequately coordinated
with other key market mechanisms; and
(3) an assessment of the readiness of the
demand response programs that will be
called on to reduce the number and
severity of shortage pricing
requirements and help to mitigate
market power.146 While each of these is
a worthy goal, our intent in this
proceeding is to establish a set of broad
criteria to serve as a general guideline
for all RTOs and ISOs on designing a
shortage pricing approach. Nothing will
prevent RTOs, ISOs and their
stakeholders from considering these
goals in the process of drafting their
compliance proposal, and indeed, we
encourage them to do so if these items
are of concern to them. Further, we note
that the Final Rule required RTOs and
ISOs to address market power issues in
their compliance filings, and to provide
‘‘an adequate factual record
demonstrating that provisions exist for
mitigating market power and deterring
gaming behavior * * * [, which] could
include, but is not limited to, the use of
demand resources to discipline bidding
behavior to competitive levels during an
operating reserve shortage.’’ 147
Accordingly, we find that the
Commission did not err in rejecting
PG&E’s narrower request for a readiness
assessment.
mstockstill on DSKH9S0YB1PROD with RULES2
B. Long-Term Power Contracting in
Organized Markets
107. In the Final Rule, the
Commission established a requirement
that RTOs and ISOs dedicate a portion
of their Web sites for market
participants to post offers to buy and
sell electric energy on a long-term basis.
The Commission noted that this
requirement was designed to improve
transparency in the contracting process
so as to encourage long-term contracting
for electric power.148 Requests for
rehearing were timely filed with respect
to the need to require development of
new hedging instruments and to the
need for the Commission to address the
larger structural causes of problems
with the long-term contracting market.
146 Id.
P 244.
P 196.
148 Id. P 307.
147 Id.
VerDate Nov<24>2008
18:36 Jul 28, 2009
Jkt 217001
1. Hedging Instruments
108. Several commenters argued in
their NOPR comments that the
Commission should address the lack of
certain financial hedging instruments in
organized markets. These commenters
argued that providing such hedging
instruments would reduce the risk of
marginal losses and encourage longterm contracting. In the Final Rule,
however, the Commission declined to
take any action on hedging
instruments.149
a. Request for Rehearing
109. SMUD argues in its request for
rehearing that exposure to marginal
losses, like exposure to congestion
charges, poses a substantial risk to
market participants interested in longterm bilateral contracts. The absence of
a hedging mechanism for marginal
losses, SMUD states, is a significant risk
factor in long-term contracting. SMUD
notes that the Commission encouraged,
but did not require, RTOs and ISOs to
develop such hedging mechanisms. It
argues that this encouragement is not
sufficient, and that the Commission
should address on rehearing the need
for a marginal loss hedging mechanism
or explain why one is not needed.150
b. Commission Determination
110. The Commission addressed
previously SMUD’s request for a
requirement for a marginal loss hedging
instrument in Order No. 681.151 The
Commission found that EPAct 2005
does not require a marginal loss hedge,
and that due to the nature of marginal
losses, it is more difficult to design a
hedge for marginal losses than it is to
create one for congestion costs.152 The
Commission again addressed SMUD’s
request in the order conditionally
approving revisions to CAISO’s Market
Redesign and Technology Upgrade
Tariff provisions involving congestion
revenue rights.153 In that order, the
Commission found that it would be
unreasonable to direct the CAISO to
provide a mechanism that is not
required by EPAct 2005, and that does
not yet exist in workable form
elsewhere.154 In light of the
Commission’s extensive, and recent,
consideration of this issue, and SMUD’s
149 Id.
150 SMUD
at 7.
Firm Transmission Rights in
Organized Electricity Markets, Order No. 681, FERC
Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,226, order on reh’g, Order No.
681–A, 117 FERC ¶ 61,201 (2006).
152 Order No. 681–A, 117 FERC ¶ 61,201 at P 105.
153 Cal. Indep. Sys. Operator Corp., 120 FERC
¶ 61,023, at P 229 (2007), reh’g denied, 124 FERC
¶ 61,094 (2008).
154 Id.
PO 00000
151 Long-Term
Frm 00017
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
37791
failure to propose new arguments here
including evidence of a relevant change
in circumstances, or a workable hedge
for marginal losses, we are not
persuaded to grant rehearing. We
continue to encourage RTOs and ISOs to
explore methods by which they can
assist load-serving entities and others to
obtain hedges for marginal losses.155
2. Structural Issues
111. The Commission received
comments prior to the Final Rule
arguing that the structure of organized
markets was flawed, and advocating that
the Commission needed to institute a
broader investigation of organized
markets to protect consumers. In the
Final Rule, the Commission stated that
many of the broader issues commenters
raised were beyond the scope of the
proceeding, and would require further
development to be ripe for inclusion in
a proceeding. The Commission noted
that these issues had been the subject of
a technical conference held to discuss
the proposals of American Forest &
Paper Association and Portland Cement
Association.156 The Commission stated
that it continues to review the
information it received at the technical
conference for possible action.
a. Request for Rehearing
112. APPA–CMUA argue that the
Commission erroneously failed to
expand the scope of this proceeding to
investigate the issue of whether RTO
markets are producing just and
reasonable rates. They argue that
sections 205 and 206 of the Federal
Power Act require the Commission to
act when it finds evidence of unjust and
unreasonable rates.157
113. APPA–CMUA note that they,
along with other consumer entities,
presented evidence to the Commission
in this proceeding regarding failures in
centralized power markets. These
failures include fewer and higher-priced
long-term power supply options, the
shifting of financial risks to customers,
and impediments to construction of new
generation resources. APPA–CMUA
argue that the Commission did not
consider this evidence, but instead
found that the scope of the proceeding
was limited to four ‘‘discrete’’ areas.
APPA filed extensive comments asking
the Commission to expand the scope of
the proceeding, which it argues were
ignored. APPA–CMUA note that APPA
also filed comments following the
155 Order
No. 681–A, 117 FERC ¶ 61,201 at P 106.
Notice of Technical Conference,
Capacity Markets in Regions with Organized
Electric Markets, Docket No. AD08–4–000 (April 25,
2008).
157 APPA–CMUA at 3.
156 Supplemental
E:\FR\FM\29JYR2.SGM
29JYR2
37792
Federal Register / Vol. 74, No. 144 / Wednesday, July 29, 2009 / Rules and Regulations
technical conference held on May 7,
2008, but that there has been no further
activity in that docket.158
114. APPA–CMUA argue that the
Commission’s failure to act violates its
obligations under the Federal Power
Act, and under administrative law
generally. They argue that the
Commission has a duty to address
unjust and unreasonable rates that
extends to systemic, marketwide
problems.159 They also argue that the
Commission has a legal obligation to
investigate if evidence is presented to it
that unjust and unreasonable rates are
being charged; if the investigation
reveals unjust and unreasonable rates,
contracts or practices, the Commission
must take remedial action.160 APPA–
CMUA cite to the recent United States
Supreme Court case in Massachusetts v.
EPA, in which the Court found that the
EPA possessed not only the statutory
authority, but also the responsibility, to
regulate greenhouse gas emissions.161
APPA–CMUA state that the Court found
that the EPA’s refusal to institute a
rulemaking to regulate greenhouse gases
contradicted the clear terms of the Clean
Air Act, and was arbitrary and
capricious. Similarly, they argue, the
Commission in this proceeding has not
only failed to act, it has failed even to
look at the many comments, statements,
studies and affidavits in the docket
alleging unjust and unreasonable
rates.162
115. APPA–CMUA also argue that the
Commission erred in finding that RTO
and ISO markets provide demonstrable
benefits to customers. They argue that
the Commission cites no support for the
finding, and point to evidence in the
record from wholesale customers and
others calling into question the
existence of such benefits. APPA–
CMUA cite to the 2008 GAO Report,
which they argue found that the
Commission has not done the analyses
necessary to support its assertions that
RTO markets provide demonstrable
benefits to wholesale customers and
consumers.163
116. Finally, APPA–CMUA argue that
the Commission failed to address the
structural causes underlying the lack of
long-term contracting in RTO and ISO
regions. They note that the Commission
158 Id.
at 21.
at 25 (citing Transmission Access Policy
Study Group v. FERC, 225 F.3d 667, 686–87 (D.C.
Cir. 2000); Associated Gas Distribs. v. FERC, 824
F.2d 981, 1008 (D.C. Cir. 1987)).
160 Id. at 26 (citing Order No. 2000, FERC Stats
& Regs at 31,043 n.163).
161 549 U.S. 497 (2008).
162 APPA–CMUA at 28.
163 Id. at 32 (citing 2008 GAO Report). See supra
note 129.
mstockstill on DSKH9S0YB1PROD with RULES2
159 Id.
VerDate Nov<24>2008
18:36 Jul 28, 2009
Jkt 217001
received several comments relating to
the over-reliance on spot markets and
lack of long-term contracts caused by
the structure of markets within the RTO
system. However, the Commission
declined to order any of the broader
measures commenters suggested.
APPA–CMUA argue that the
Commission’s statement that these
structural issues were beyond the scope
of the proceeding was a non sequitur,
since the Commission itself had set the
scope of the proceeding. They note the
Commission’s apparent belief that there
is no fundamental problem with longterm contracts, that contracts are merely
available at higher prices than in the
past. However APPA–CMUA argue that
the Commission failed to consider the
results of the Synapse Study it
presented, which found that there were
structural reasons beyond changes in
fuel supply that drove buyer reluctance
to enter into long-term contracts. They
also argue that the current turmoil in the
credit markets should cause the
Commission to reconsider its decision,
as it is going to be difficult to finance
new generation facilities in the future
without long-term contracts to support
them.164 APPA–CMUA conclude that
the Commission effectively ignored
many comments, statements, studies
and affidavits that indicate that many
load-side interests believe that RTOs are
charging unjust and unreasonable rates,
and that those comments never received
the due process that the FPA requires.
b. Commission Determination
117. We find that the Commission did
not violate the standards of due process
or shirk its duty under the FPA in
confining the scope of this proceeding
to four specific areas of reform related
to the operation of competitive
wholesale markets. We deny rehearing
on the issue of whether the Commission
failed to justify its decision not to
expand the scope of this proceeding.
118. APPA–CMUA’s argument that
the Commission has a legal duty to
expand this rulemaking proceeding to
address whether and how to
systemically revise organized markets is
mistaken. As the Supreme Court has
ruled, an agency has broad discretion to
choose how best to marshal its limited
resources and personnel to carry out its
delegated responsibilities.165 While
APPA–CMUA cite to the Supreme
Court’s decision in Massachusetts v.
EPA, this decision was based on a
specific statute related to EPA action on
greenhouse gases, and did not overturn
at 34–36.
Chevron U.S.A. Inc. v. NRDC, 467 U.S.
837, 842–845 (1984).
PO 00000
164 Id.
165 See
Frm 00018
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
the general rule that agencies have
discretion over how to act to carry out
their responsibilities.166 The Supreme
Court found that the EPA had refused to
act on a specific statutory requirement
to regulate greenhouse gases, and that
its refusal was not warranted by the
statutory text.167 By contrast, the
Commission has not refused its
responsibility to ensure just and
reasonable rates here. Indeed, FPA
sections 205 and 206 form the legal
basis for this proceeding.168
119. As the Commission stated in the
Final Rule, this proceeding was not
intended to fundamentally redesign
organized markets; rather, the reforms
were intended to be incremental
improvements to the ongoing operation
of organized markets without undoing
or upsetting the significant efforts that
have already been made in providing
demonstrable benefits to wholesale
customers.169 The Commission focused
on four discrete areas with the goal of
improving competition in organized
wholesale electric markets. This
determination was based in part upon a
desire to create a manageable forum for
discussing and implementing those
revisions to organized wholesale
markets that could be implemented
relatively soon. Expanding the scope of
the proceeding to encompass the
wholesale revision of organized RTO or
ISO markets would delay the immediate
and necessary market reforms ordered
in the Final Rule.
120. We disagree with APPA–CMUA’s
argument that the Commission has
denied it due process by declining to
investigate wholesale market operations
in general on the basis that doing so is
outside the scope of the proceeding that
the Commission itself set. If the
Commission was obligated to frame
every investigation to satisfy
commenters’ requests, individual
commenters would have the power to
delay or derail nascent market rules
with which they disagreed merely by
arguing that the scope of the proceeding
was too narrow or too broad. The
Commission’s goal here is to make
improvements to four areas of wholesale
market operations.
121. The fact that this proceeding is
limited to the four topics addressed
above does not indicate that the
Commission refuses to act in other areas
to ensure just and reasonable rates. For
example, the Commission has acted on
166 See
Massachusetts v. EPA, 549 U.S. at 527.
at 530.
168 See Order No. 719, FERC Stats. & Regs.
¶ 31,281 at P 13.
169 Id. P 2; NOPR, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 32,628
at P 4, 282.
167 Id.
E:\FR\FM\29JYR2.SGM
29JYR2
Federal Register / Vol. 74, No. 144 / Wednesday, July 29, 2009 / Rules and Regulations
a generic basis and with regard to
specific regional markets to, among
other things, address transmission
planning reforms, interconnection rules,
and reform of capacity markets, all areas
that improve long-term contracting and
organized markets as a whole.170 The
Commission continues to review other
proposals for reforms, including
additional reforms to remove barriers to
demand response and reform organized
markets.171 We have received a wealth
of information on all sides of these
issues, from comments in this
proceeding and others, testimony at
technical conferences, and other reports
such as the recent GAO Report
discussed above. Contrary to the claims
of APPA–CMUA, the Commission
considered all of the comments,
statements, studies and affidavits
received in this docket when
determining the scope and outcome of
this proceeding.172 We appreciate the
time and effort put into those
submissions, and we remain receptive
to the avenues of reform proposed
therein.
122. The Commission’s policy
continues to be to promote competition
in wholesale electric power markets.
This policy is in keeping with
Commission practice and was ratified
by Congress in EPAct 2005.173 We
always welcome suggestions for
concrete actions that could be taken to
improve competition in wholesale
markets.
mstockstill on DSKH9S0YB1PROD with RULES2
C. Market-Monitoring Policies
123. The Commission ordered a
number of reforms in the Final Rule
designed to enhance the market
monitoring function and thereby to
improve the performance and
transparency of the organized markets.
These reforms centered upon two areas:
ensuring the independence of market
monitoring units (MMUs) and
expanding their information sharing
function.
124. To increase the independence of
MMUs, the Final Rule directed that
MMUs in most instances report directly
to the RTO or ISO board of directors or
to a committee of the board, rather than
to management; directed tariff inclusion
of a duty on the part of the RTO or ISO
to provide the MMU with access to the
170 See Order No. 719, FERC Stats. & Regs.
¶ 31,281 at P 280.
171 For instance, the Commission recently held a
technical conference on credit issues affecting the
electric power industry. Technical Conference on
Credit and Capital Issues Affecting the Electricity
Power Industry, Docket No. AD09–2–000 (Jan. 13,
2009).
172 NOPR, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 32,628 at P 16–
25.
173 Public Law 109–58, 119 Stat. 594.
VerDate Nov<24>2008
18:36 Jul 28, 2009
Jkt 217001
data, resources and personnel needed to
perform its duties; required the RTO or
ISO to set out the expanded functions of
the MMU in its tariff; removed the
MMU from tariff administration and
modified MMU market mitigation
functions; prescribed protocols for the
referral to Commission staff by the
MMU both of market design flaws and
of suspected wrongdoing; and required
the RTO or ISO to adopt ethics
standards for the MMUs and MMU
employees.174
125. Within the area of information
sharing, the Final Rule required the
MMU to make quarterly reports in
addition to the annual state of the
market report, to expand the recipients
for the reports, and to hold regular
telephone conferences among the MMU
and Commission staff, RTO or ISO staff,
interested State commissions, State
attorneys general and market
participants; established procedures for
the MMU to share information with
State commissions; and reduced the lag
time for the release of offer and bid data
by the RTO or ISO.175
126. Requests for rehearing or
clarification were timely filed with
respect to the following issues: MMU
involvement in market mitigation, the
relationship between the internal and
external MMU, State access to MMU
information, release of offer and bid
data, and the scope of the ethics
provisions. In addition, the Commission
on its own motion clarifies certain
duties of the MMU with respect to the
referral of market design flaws. These
are discussed below.
1. Market Mitigation
127. In the Final Rule, the
Commission modified the proposal
made in the NOPR that MMUs should
be removed from market mitigation.
That proposal had been designed to
remove the MMU from subordination to
the RTO or ISO, and to eliminate the
conflict of interest inherent in an MMU
opining on the health of the market
while itself influencing the market by
conducting mitigation. However, a
number of commenters objected that
there might be a greater conflict of
interest in having the RTO or ISO
administer mitigation, as it has a vested
interest in accommodating its market
participants. Commenters raised a
number of other objections, including
the arguments that the MMU is better
equipped than the RTO or ISO to detect
the need for mitigation, and that
removing the MMU from mitigation
174 Order No. 719, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,281
at P 317 et seq.
175 Id. P 395 et seq.
PO 00000
Frm 00019
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
37793
would distance it from the market
insights it needs for its monitoring
function.
128. In order to preserve the
advantages of allowing the MMU to
perform mitigation, while avoiding
entangling it in a conflict of interest, the
Final Rule struck a balance between the
extremes of removing the MMU entirely
from mitigation and allowing unfettered
MMU mitigation. It did this in part by
providing that an RTO or ISO with a
hybrid MMU structure 176 may permit
its internal MMU to conduct mitigation,
so long as its external MMU is assigned
the task of monitoring the quality and
appropriateness of that mitigation. In
addition, the Final Rule provided that if
the RTO or ISO does not have a hybrid
structure, it may still allow its MMU to
perform retrospective mitigation, while
relegating prospective mitigation to
itself. The Final Rule further provided
that the MMU could provide the inputs
required by the RTO or ISO for
prospective mitigation, including the
determination of reference levels, the
identification of system constraints,
calculation of costs, and the like.
a. Requests for Rehearing
129. Old Dominion objects to the
removal of prospective mitigation from
non-hybrid MMUs, contending that the
Commission failed to demonstrate a
conflict of interest on the part of MMUs
while ignoring what Old Dominion sees
as a conflict of interest arising from the
RTOs conducting mitigation on what
are, in effect, their own customers.177
130. Pennsylvania PUC argues that
prospective mitigation should not be
limited to RTOs and ISOs with hybrid
MMUs.178 It contends that mitigation is
performed according to objective tariff
criteria, removing the element of
discretion, and argues that the record
does not establish a need for placing
limitations on the performance of
mitigation by MMUs.179
131. Industrial Coalitions assert that
the Commission should not have
removed tariff administration and
mitigation from the duties of the MMU,
arguing that although the Commission
intended to strengthen market
monitoring, it achieved the opposite
effect. They advance the opinion that
RTOs and ISOs have demonstrated a
176 A hybrid MMU structure is one with both an
internal and an external market monitor. An
internal market monitor is one that is composed of
RTO or ISO employees, an external market monitor
is an independent entity that conducts market
monitoring for the RTO or ISO pursuant to a
contract.
177 Old Dominion at 6–7.
178 Pennsylvania PUC at 5–6.
179 Id. at 3.
E:\FR\FM\29JYR2.SGM
29JYR2
37794
Federal Register / Vol. 74, No. 144 / Wednesday, July 29, 2009 / Rules and Regulations
preference for unmitigated outcomes,
and therefore should not be given total
responsibility for identifying and
rectifying abuses of market power.180
132. The Ohio PUC and Wisconsin
PSC object to what they see as the
internal MMU within a hybrid MMU
structure having greater mitigation
authority than an external MMU.181 The
Ohio PUC opines that some (internal)
MMUs will not have the necessary tools
to accomplish their job function, which
will limit their ability to impose
prospective mitigation.182
mstockstill on DSKH9S0YB1PROD with RULES2
b. Commission Determination
133. The Commission affirms the
determination made in the Final Rule as
to MMU involvement in mitigation. The
arguments raised by petitioners were
extensively discussed in comments
made during the rulemaking process,
and were taken into account by the
Commission in reaching its resolution of
the issue. The MMU’s conflict of
interest in conducting mitigation, which
one petitioner contends has not been
demonstrated, is inherent in the nature
of the MMU’s duties: inasmuch as the
MMU must opine on the quality of its
own mitigation when it reports on the
health and state of the markets, it cannot
be expected to be entirely objective.
Conflict of interest concerns do not
necessarily rely on historical instances
of abuse, but rather on the existence of
the conflict itself and on the wellknown tendency of human nature to see
one’s own actions in a favorable light.
Furthermore, contrary to that same
petitioner’s assertion, the Commission
did take into account the argument that
RTOs and ISOs have conflicts of their
own in conducting mitigation. That
consideration was, in fact, part of the
basis for permitting a substantial degree
of mitigation to be performed by the
MMUs, both internal and external.183
134. Pennsylvania PUC claims that
mitigation is non-discretionary, and
concludes there is no danger of a
conflict of interest influencing the MMU
in conducting mitigation.184 The
Commission is of the view that the more
objective the criteria for mitigation
become, the better and fairer their
application will be. However, we realize
that there is still a degree of judgment
involved in determining whether
mitigation is appropriate. If this were
not so, mitigation could be entirely
automatic, which is not the case.
180 Industrial
Coalitions at 12–14.
PUC at 14–15; Wisconsin PSC at 2–3.
182 Ohio PUC at 15.
183 Order No. 719, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,281
at P 370–79.
184 Pennsylvania PUC at 3.
181 Ohio
VerDate Nov<24>2008
20:07 Jul 28, 2009
Jkt 217001
Therefore, conflicts of interest must still
be a part of the Commission’s
consideration in fashioning its rules.
135. The assertion of Industrial
Coalitions that RTOs and ISOs have
demonstrated a preference for
unmitigated outcomes has not been
substantiated with record evidence.
Other factors can have the opposite
effect on an RTO’s or ISO’s decision to
mitigate, such as achieving price
moderation, ensuring the orderly and
fair administration of the markets, and
avoiding MMU referrals to Commission
staff due to lax administration. In this
regard it is important to observe that any
mitigation performed by the RTO or ISO
will be monitored by the MMU, and, if
the RTO or ISO is not performing its job
properly, it will be the duty of the MMU
to refer the conduct to Commission staff.
136. Ohio PUC and Wisconsin PSC
assume that in an RTO or ISO with a
hybrid MMU, the internal MMU has
been given more authority in the
mitigation area than the external MMU.
However, the Final Rule’s mitigation
provisions provide that the external
MMU in a hybrid MMU structure must
independently evaluate the performance
of the internal MMU, if the latter
conducts mitigation. Thus, the external
MMU arguably has more authority in
the mitigation area than the internal
MMU, rather than less.
137. For all the foregoing reasons, the
Commission concludes that its
resolution of the mitigation and tariff
administration issues raised in the
NOPR struck the correct balance
between unfettered MMU mitigation
and no mitigation by the MMU.
Therefore, we affirm the Final Rule in
this regard and decline to grant
rehearing on the issue of MMU
involvement in market mitigation.
2. Relationship Between Internal and
External MMU
138. The Final Rule did not express
a preference for a particular market
monitoring structure, whether internal,
external, or hybrid. The Commission
observed that in light of regional
variances and preferences in this regard,
each RTO and ISO should decide for
itself its own MMU structural
relationship. However, the Final Rule
did make certain distinctions,
depending on the particular MMU
structure, as to various duties and
responsibilities, including reporting to
the board of directors and conducting
market mitigation.185
185 Order No. 719, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,281
at P 374.
PO 00000
Frm 00020
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
a. Requests for Rehearing
139. Ohio PUC questions the efficacy
of a hybrid MMU, and proposes that an
external market monitor’s evaluations
and recommendations should prevail
over those of the internal MMU. It
proposes that mitigation authority not
be vested in the internal MMU,
presumably because it believes that the
internal MMU lacks independence.186
Ohio PUC also suggests that the
responsibilities for data collection,
analysis, and all market mitigation and
referrals should take place at the
external MMU level.187 It argues that
RTOs and ISOs should identify in their
tariffs all MMU functions that are
essential to the effective operation of the
MMU, and delegate them to the external
or independent MMU.188 Ohio PUC
argues that the Final Rule results in a
dysfunctional MMU hierarchy that will
make the existing MMU subordinate to
any new internal MMU and the RTO or
ISO.189
140. Wisconsin PSC supports in their
entirety the requests of Ohio PUC. It
asserts that the Commission erred in
supposedly vesting more authority in
the internal MMU in a hybrid structure
than in the external MMU, and in failing
to clarify that all MMU rules and
enforcement standards identified in the
RTO or ISO tariff be entrusted to the
external MMU.190
b. Commission Determination
141. The proposals by petitioners
favoring an external MMU appear to be
predicated on the notion that an internal
MMU necessarily lacks independence.
However, as we observed in the Final
Rule, we have not detected any
deficiency in performance by internal
MMUs that is attributable to their
structure.191 Furthermore, the
proposition that internal MMUs lack
independence ignores the very reforms
directed in the Final Rule, one of which
provides that an internal MMU that is
not part of a hybrid structure must
report to the board of directors or to a
committee of the board, rather than to
management. An internal MMU within
a hybrid structure may report to
management, but only if it does not
perform any of the three core MMU
functions, those being identifying
ineffective market rules, reviewing the
performance of the markets, and making
186 Ohio
PUC at 13.
at 13–16.
188 Id. at 16–17.
189 Id. at 14. We assume here that ‘‘existing
MMU’’ means an external MMU.
190 Wisconsin PSC at 2–3.
191 Order No. 719, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,281
at P 327.
187 Id.
E:\FR\FM\29JYR2.SGM
29JYR2
Federal Register / Vol. 74, No. 144 / Wednesday, July 29, 2009 / Rules and Regulations
mstockstill on DSKH9S0YB1PROD with RULES2
referrals to the Commission. This reform
was instituted precisely to bolster the
independence of the MMU performing
the core MMU functions.
142. In addition, in a hybrid MMU
structure, the internal MMU may
conduct market mitigation only if the
external MMU is assigned the
responsibility and given the tools to
monitor the quality and appropriateness
of that mitigation. Thus, the external
MMU can determine whether mitigation
is being adequately performed and, if
any deficiencies persist, refer the
situation to the Commission.
Consequently, the Commission
disagrees that a hybrid MMU, with the
internal MMU conducting mitigation,
will be inferior in performance and
independence to an external MMU.
143. The Commission also disagrees
with Wisconsin PSC’s contention that
the internal MMU in a hybrid structure
is vested with more authority than the
external MMU. As noted above,
mitigation may be assigned to the
internal MMU within a hybrid structure
only if the external MMU is given the
tools and responsibility to monitor it,
thus arguably giving the external MMU
greater authority than the internal
MMU. As to other market monitoring
duties, these are to be allocated between
an internal and external MMU (in a
hybrid structure) by the RTO or ISO,
with stakeholder approval. Therefore, if
petitioners desire that the external
MMU should be assigned more of the
core MMU functions, they should raise
those concerns in the stakeholder
process. But whatever allocation results
from such process, the Final Rule
provides for checks and balances to
ensure oversight over the internal
MMU’s performance, whether by the
external MMU or by the board of
directors. For all these reasons, we
decline to grant the requests for
rehearing on the issue of the
relationship between external and
internal MMUs.
3. State Access to MMU Information
144. One of the two principal goals of
the Final Rule’s MMU reforms was to
expand the content and dissemination
of MMU information. One such
expansion consists of providing a means
by which State commissions can request
tailored information from the MMUs.
The Commission placed certain
restrictions on this right, such as
limiting them to general market trends
and information, and prohibiting them
from being used for State enforcement
purposes.192 This was done so that the
MMUs would not be overwhelmed by
192 Id.
P 446–59.
VerDate Nov<24>2008
18:36 Jul 28, 2009
Jkt 217001
such requests at the expense of doing
their primary job, and to preserve
confidentiality where warranted.
Because of confidentiality concerns, and
also to encourage cooperation by both
existing and potential subjects of
investigations, the Commission declined
to change its policy providing that
MMU referrals to the Commission
remain confidential.
a. Requests for Rehearing
145. Illinois Commerce Commission
argues that tailored requests for
information to the MMU by State
commissions should not be restricted to
general market trends and information,
and further contends that there is no
evidence that other requests would be
time consuming and burdensome.193
Illinois Commerce Commission also
argues that the Commission should not
restrict the dissemination of raw data, or
forbid State commissions from obtaining
information from MMUs for State
enforcement activities, as this may
conflict with Illinois Commerce
Commission’s ability under existing
tariffs to request MMU information from
Midwest ISO or PJM.194 Lastly, Illinois
Commerce Commission proposes that
State commissions be informed when an
MMU refers a matter concerning market
conduct to the Commission. Illinois
Commerce Commission argues that
there would be no disincentive to
entities to self-report if the Commission
did so, and contends that State
commissions have a proven track record
of properly handling confidential
information.195 Minnesota PUC
supports the Illinois Commerce
Commission’s requests in their
entirety.196
b. Commission Determination
146. Contrary to the assertions in the
requests for rehearing, the new
provision granting State commissions
the right to make tailored requests for
information broadens their access to
MMU data, rather than restricting it.
Objections of the type expressed by
Illinois Commerce Commission were
addressed in the Final Rule and
rejected.197 While the information
sought in tailored requests for
information should relate to general
market trends and the performance of
the wholesale market, the Commission
pointed out that the type of information
to be provided by the MMU may vary
from region to region, and is governed
193 Illinois
principally by the workload such
requests impose on the MMU.
Therefore, as discussed in the Final
Rule, unless the information violates
confidentiality restrictions regarding
commercially sensitive material, is
designed to aid State enforcement
actions, or impinges on the
confidentiality rules of the Commission
with regard to referrals, it may be
produced, so long as it does not
interfere with the MMU’s ability to carry
out its core functions. Subject to these
limitations, granting or refusing such
requests will be at the MMU’s
discretion, based on agreements worked
out between the RTO or ISO and the
States, and subject to the confidentiality
provisions in the RTO’s or ISO’s tariff
and to the Commission’s confidentiality
restrictions.198
147. The Commission respectfully
disagrees that the confidentiality
provisions of the Commission and of the
RTOs and ISOs may be overridden,
simply because a State asserts it is
subject to statutory or regulatory
provisions regulating the release of
information coming into its possession.
The MMUs should not be placed in the
position of researching the intricacies of
State law on the subject, or predicting
how a court might rule on the disclosure
of material once it enters the possession
of a State commission. While Illinois
Commerce Commission contends that
the confidentiality provisions of the
Final Rule ‘‘may conflict’’ with existing
procedures within Midwest ISO and
PJM, it fails to explain how. Therefore,
no factual basis has been presented
upon which to address this objection.
148. As to the time-consuming nature
of requests made for State enforcement
purposes, the Commission provided
evidence in the record to that effect,
citing the agency’s own long experience
with investigations.199 Furthermore, it
would be difficult if not impossible to
provide information tailored for
enforcement purposes without
breaching confidentiality, as such
information would be directed toward
the activities of individual market
participants. As to raw data, the
Commission did not forbid an MMU
from providing raw data (properly
redacted for confidentiality purposes),
but stated that if the gathering,
organizing, reviewing, and explaining of
such data would be too consuming, the
MMU was not required to provide it.200
This is a subset of the Commission’s
Commerce Commission at 4–5.
194 Id.
at 2–4.
196 Minnesota PUC at 1.
197 Order No. 719, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,281
at P 446–59.
PO 00000
37795
195 Id.
Frm 00021
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
198 State commissions have the further safety
valve of seeking otherwise proscribed information
by filing a request with the Commission. Id. P 458.
199 Id. P 452.
200 Id. P 450.
E:\FR\FM\29JYR2.SGM
29JYR2
37796
Federal Register / Vol. 74, No. 144 / Wednesday, July 29, 2009 / Rules and Regulations
expressed concern that the MMU not be
diverted from its primary MMU duties
by requests for information and analysis
from State actors.
149. In the Final Rule, the
Commission declined to change its longstanding policy of maintaining the
confidentiality of MMU referrals to
Commission staff. Illinois Commerce
Commission contends there would be
no disincentive to companies to selfreport if such referrals were made
public, because MMU referrals do not
occur as a result of self-reports. We
disagree. If an entity sees that formerly
non-public investigations are now being
made public, it will be discouraged not
only from making self-reports in the
future, but also from cooperating and
providing data in existing and any
future investigations, regardless of the
origin of that investigation.
Furthermore, as pointed out in the Final
Rule, such disclosure could also injure
innocent persons who might be
erroneously implicated or adversely
affected by simply being associated with
an investigation.201
150. For all these reasons, the
Commission declines to grant the
requests for rehearing on the issue of
tailored requests for information and
referrals to the Commission.
4. Offer and Bid Data
151. In the Final Rule, the
Commission shortened the period for
release of offer and bid data to three
months,202 while retaining the policy of
masking the identity of the participants.
The Final Rule also incorporated
flexibility by allowing RTOs and ISOs to
propose a shorter release time or, if they
could demonstrate a danger of
collusion, a four-month instead of a
three-month release, or some alternative
mechanism if release of a report were
otherwise to occur in the same season
as reflected in the data.
mstockstill on DSKH9S0YB1PROD with RULES2
a. Requests for Rehearing or
Clarification
152. TAPS believes that the reduction
of the release period to three months is
a step in the right direction,203 but does
not think it goes far enough. It requests
more rapid release of offer and bid data,
as well as the unmasking of identities.
TAPS cites to Australia, England and
Wales, all of which it states release data
on a near-real-time basis,204 and
contends that information transparency
can play a role in the potential
201 Id.
P 465.
RTOs and ISOs have a six-month release
202 Most
policy.
203 TAPS at 56.
204 Id. at 57.
VerDate Nov<24>2008
18:36 Jul 28, 2009
Jkt 217001
mitigation of collusion.205 TAPS
theorizes that the early release of data
levels the playing field for smaller
market participants and enables them to
assist with market monitoring,206 and
argues that greater transparency may
help expose attempts to manipulate the
market.207
153. APPA–CMUA, in a joint filing,
support the immediate and full
disclosure of offer and bid data, the
unmasking of the identity of bidders,
and disclosure of system lambdas.208
They cite the Dunn Study,209 which the
Commission discussed in the Final
Rule, for the propositions that ‘‘the
possible benefits’’ of posting offer and
bid data on the day following the
operating day ‘‘appear to far exceed’’ the
risks of collusion, and that such release
may help expose market
manipulation.210 With respect to the
unmasking of identities, APPA–CMUA
argue that although the Commission
provided that RTOs and ISOs may
propose a period when such unmasking
might be permitted, this will not happen
because generators will argue against
such disclosure in the stakeholder
process.211 They further argue that
requiring the filing of system lambdas
would allow direct analysis of RTO and
ISO real-time prices in comparison to
the relevant underlying variable
generation costs.212
154. Illinois Commerce Commission
objects to the Commission’s
continuation of the policy of masking
the identities of market participants,
and proposes as an alternative that
identities be unmasked after a fourmonth lag, asserting that this time lag
would eliminate concerns about
participant harm and collusive
behavior.213 The Illinois Commerce
Commission contends that an entity’s
bidding strategy is an important piece of
market information, useful in analyzing
the reasonableness of market
outcomes.214
155. Minnesota PUC supports the
request for rehearing by the Illinois
Commerce Commission in its
entirety.215
at 58.
at 59.
207 Id. at 60.
208 ‘‘System lambda’’ is defined as the variable
cost of the last kilowatt produced over a particular
hour. APPA–CMUA at 39.
209 Id. at 15–16.
210 Id. at 37–38.
211 Id. at 38.
212 Id. at 39.
213 Illinois Commerce Commission at 8.
214 Id. at 7.
215 Minnesota PUC at 1.
PO 00000
205 Id.
206 Id.
Frm 00022
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
b. Commission Determination
156. Petitioners’ objections on this
issue were addressed in the Final Rule,
and the Commission sees no reason to
revisit its determination. The Final Rule
provided RTOs and ISOs with a good
deal of flexibility to propose a lag period
that would work best for its particular
situation, and that would meet the
desires of its stakeholders. Under the
Final Rule, RTOs and ISOs, should they
desire, are free to propose petitioners’
preferred lag period of only one day.216
157. APPA–CMUA contend that
generators would object to such a
proposal, and would be able to sway the
stakeholder process against it. This
argument implicitly suggests, without
evidence, that not only would the
stakeholder process reach a biased and
unjust result, but that their proposal is
the only correct one. It is also quite
possible that the stakeholder process
will result in a balancing of petitioners’
concerns against those of market
participants who may have perfectly
rational reasons to prefer delaying the
release of offer and bid data, and to
mask identities. For example, one such
reason is the fact that trading strategies,
which is exactly the information sought
by petitioners, are trade secrets that
have considerable value to market
participants. While the Illinois
Commerce Commission may wish to use
the data for enforcement purposes, other
entities may use it to give themselves a
competitive advantage, or to eliminate
the competitive advantage of another
entity. Since the various stakeholders
have different concerns and interests,
balancing those concerns is more suited
to exploration and resolution in the
stakeholder process than in this
proceeding, at least in the first
instance.217
158. Likewise, the Final Rule affords
flexibility in the area of the masking of
identities of market participants placing
offer and bid data, by providing that
RTOs and ISOs may propose a period
for the eventual unmasking of such
identities.218 Again, this allows for a
balancing of interests in the stakeholder
process. The Commission built this
flexibility into its determinations in the
area of offer and bid data both to take
into account regional differences, and to
216 Order No. 719, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,281
at P 424.
217 The fact that ISO–NE proposed reducing the
lag time for release of offer and bid data from six
months to three months is evidence of the fact that
the stakeholder process is not necessarily geared
toward less disclosure. See ISO New England Inc.
and New England Power Pool, 121 FERC ¶ 61,035
(2007).
218 Order No. 719, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,281
at P 423.
E:\FR\FM\29JYR2.SGM
29JYR2
Federal Register / Vol. 74, No. 144 / Wednesday, July 29, 2009 / Rules and Regulations
give the industry a chance to work with
the release period mandated in the Final
Rule before deciding whether to propose
an even shorter period. Certainly, if an
RTO or ISO believes it desirable to
release offer and bid data on the day
following the operating day, nothing in
the Final Rule prevents it from making
such a proposal to the Commission,
with appropriate justification; in fact, as
indicated in the Final Rule, this may be
done in the compliance filing to be
made in this docket.
159. For all these reasons, the
Commission declines to grant the
requests for rehearing on the issue of
offer and bid data.
5. Ethics Provisions
160. In the Final Rule, the
Commission enumerated a number of
minimum ethics standards that the
RTOs and ISOs are required to adopt for
MMUs and their employees.219 In
response to comments filed by the
Midwest ISO and Potomac Economics,
both of which had requested
clarification that any adopted ethics
standards need not prohibit MMU
employees from performing monitoring
for non-RTO or ISO entities, the
Commission drew a distinction in the
preamble of the Final Rule between
entities within and without the RTO or
ISO monitored by the MMU. The Final
Rule clarified that a monitoring
engagement was permissible if the
employing entity were not a market
participant in the particular RTO or ISO
for which the MMU performs market
monitoring, but if the employing entity
was a market participant in the RTO or
ISO for whom the MMU does perform
market monitoring, the proposed work
would entail the same conflict of
interest as would any other consulting
services, and would not be allowed.220
mstockstill on DSKH9S0YB1PROD with RULES2
a. Request for Rehearing or Clarification
161. Potomac Economics argues that
the Commission should allow an MMU
to perform independent monitoring of
an entity other than the RTO or ISO it
monitors, whether or not such entity is
a participant in the RTO or ISO markets,
arguing that such monitoring does not
create a conflict of interest.221 Potomac
Economics contends that the
interpretation set forth in the Final Rule
would harm the MMUs, the affected
RTOs and ISOs, and the non-RTO or
ISO monitored entities, and would
eliminate synergies that would
otherwise result from such
monitoring.222 Alternatively, Potomac
Economics requests clarification as to
which ethics provision is implicated by
such activity, and whether erecting a
‘‘Chinese Wall’’ within the MMU would
resolve the concern.223
162. In support of its position,
Potomac Economics argues that the
alleged conflict of interest involved in
monitoring a non-RTO or ISO entity is
no greater than that which exists with
respect to the RTO or ISO itself,
inasmuch as in both cases the MMU is
compensated by its employer.224
Potomac Economics further observes
that such non-RTO or ISO monitoring is
done pursuant to contracts filed with
the Commission, which provide
protections against undue influence
(such as forbidding the entity from
using its budget process or the threat of
replacing the MMU as a means to exert
leverage over it).225
163. Potomac Economics also argues
that unwinding current arrangements
providing for such monitoring would
impose needless costs on the MMUs, the
RTOs and ISOs, and the monitored
entities,226 and would eliminate the
improved understanding of the RTO or
ISO markets that the MMU gleans from
its knowledge of the activities of the
monitored entity.227
participant operating in the same RTO
or ISO for activity in that RTO or ISO,
under the following conditions: The
relationship between the entity and the
MMU and the MMU’s scope of work for
the entity are both mandated by the
Commission in an order on the merits,
the contract is filed with the
Commission for review and approval,
and the contract contains a provision
that the entity must notify the
Commission of any intention to
terminate MMU employment,
permission for which may be refused by
the Commission.228
165. In light of this conclusion, it is
unnecessary to examine the alternative
requests for clarification submitted by
Potomac Economics. Furthermore,
inasmuch as the Commission’s
discussion on this point in the Final
Rule was advanced as a matter of
clarification rather than being based on
the language of the regulatory text, we
find it unnecessary to amend the
regulatory text promulgated in the Final
Rule to reach this result. For all these
reasons, the Commission grants
rehearing on this issue and clarifies the
circumstances under which an MMU
may perform monitoring services for
non-RTO and ISO entities, as set forth
in the foregoing discussion.
b. Commission Determination
164. After further consideration, the
Commission agrees that the objections
of Potomac Economics are well-taken.
To be clear, the Commission is
concerned that allowing a monitor to
oversee both the RTO or ISO as well as
a market participant operating in the
same RTO or ISO for activity in that
RTO or ISO may raise a conflict of
interest because the monitor may be
called upon to opine on its own
oversight. However, the Commission is
persuaded that the increased insights
into the RTO or ISO markets provided
by such monitoring may give the MMU
useful information, and results in the
synergies that Potomac Economics
suggests. Therefore, we grant rehearing
as set forth below. In an effort to balance
the potential benefit of synergies
resulting from the monitor overseeing
both the RTO or ISO as well as a market
participant operating in the same RTO
or ISO with our concern over potential
conflicts of interest, the Commission
will permit an RTO or ISO MMU to
enter into contracts to monitor a market
6. Referral of Market Design Flaws
166. NYISO filed an out-of-time
request for clarification regarding the
interpretation of certain language
contained in the protocols for the
referral of market design flaws to
Commission staff, which are included in
the regulatory text of the Final Rule.
Although NYISO’s request has been
rejected for untimeliness, the
Commission finds that it would be
useful to provide certain clarifications
as to when an MMU is to make referrals,
whether the referral is for suspected
wrongdoing or for the identification of
market design flaws.
167. The operative language in both
the protocols for the referral of
suspected wrongdoing and the protocols
for the identification of market design
flaws is the same; that is, an MMU is to
make such a referral ‘‘in all instances
where the Market Monitoring Unit has
222 Id.
223 Id.
at 6–7.
at 2.
225 Id. at 3.
226 Id. at 5.
227 Id.
224 Id.
219 Id.
P 383–87.
P 385.
221 Potomac Economics at 1.
220 Id.
VerDate Nov<24>2008
18:36 Jul 28, 2009
Jkt 217001
37797
PO 00000
Frm 00023
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
228 The purpose of this holding is to prevent
potential conflicts of interest that arise when the
MMU oversees its own actions. Thus, if an MMU
wants to enter into a contract to oversee the
activities of a market participant that operates
wholly outside of the RTO or ISO the MMU
oversees, the conditions in this order would not
apply. Likewise, if an MMU wants to enter into a
contract with a market participant that has activity
inside and outside of an RTO or ISO the MMU
oversees, and the MMU would only oversee the
market participant’s activity outside of that RTO or
ISO, the conditions in this order would not apply.
E:\FR\FM\29JYR2.SGM
29JYR2
37798
Federal Register / Vol. 74, No. 144 / Wednesday, July 29, 2009 / Rules and Regulations
mstockstill on DSKH9S0YB1PROD with RULES2
reason to believe’’ either that a market
violation has occurred or market design
flaws exist that the MMU believes could
effectively be remedied by rule or tariff
changes. This language is identical to
the language that is contained in the
existing protocols for referral of
suspected wrongdoing, which were
promulgated in the 2005 Policy
Statement on Market Monitoring
Units.229 The MMUs have had a number
of years to become accustomed to the
interpretation of this language, and can
apply what they have learned from the
operation of the existing protocols for
suspected wrongdoing to the new
protocols for referral of market design
flaws.
168. More specifically, this means
that the MMUs are to exercise judgment
and a certain amount of discretion in
deciding what to refer to Commission
staff. If the RTO or ISO is already aware
of the perceived market design flaw and
is timely addressing it, there is no need
for the MMU to make a referral to the
Commission (although the Commission
expects the MMU to apprise the
Commission staff on an informal basis
of important tariff changes being
contemplated by the RTO or ISO).
Likewise, if the design flaw is de
minimis, there may well be no need to
make a referral. When in doubt, the
MMU should simply call the
appropriate members of Commission
staff and discuss the issue. This
procedure will provide the MMU with
any needed guidance as to whether a
filing needs to be made.
169. We find that the foregoing
clarification does not require an
alteration to the Final Rule’s regulatory
text, which as indicated simply repeats
the language contained in the current
protocols for the referral of suspected
wrongdoing to Commission staff, and
which has historically been interpreted
in the manner indicated above.
VerDate Nov<24>2008
18:36 Jul 28, 2009
Jkt 217001
considered and, if appropriate, adopted
on a regional basis.
The Commission found that additional
criteria for responsiveness as proposed
by commenters—for example, costbenefit analyses or cost-containment
procedures—were practices and
procedures best developed by regional
entities and their stakeholders, and
therefore not necessary in our
regulations.231 However, many of the
other proposed criteria could be
a. Requests for Rehearing
172. APPA–CMUA notes that in
APPA’s comments to the NOPR, it
expressed a strong concern that the four
criteria proposed by the Commission
were so general in nature that it would
not be difficult for RTOs to assert that
they already satisfy the requirements,
and that little change would occur to
RTO responsiveness as a result.232
APPA suggested several concrete
measures that the Commission should
adopt to ensure responsiveness,
including: direct stakeholder access to
RTO boards, presentation of minority
viewpoints directly to the board,
consideration of stakeholder advisory
committees and hybrid boards, open
RTO board meetings with agendas
disclosed in advance, board member
attendance at working group/technical
meetings where appropriate,
elimination of ‘‘self-perpetuating’’ RTO
boards, administration of customer
satisfaction surveys, development of
cost oversight benchmarking for RTOs,
and a moratorium on the establishment
of new RTO-run markets unless
accompanied by an independent costbenefit analysis or affirmative vote of all
RTO stakeholder classes. APPA–CMUA
argues that because the Commission
declined to adopt additional measures,
customers seeking greater RTO
responsiveness and accountability will
have to participate in RTO stakeholder
processes with no clear guidance as to
what specific measures will satisfy the
four general criteria adopted in the Final
Rule. They seek rehearing of this aspect
of the Final Rule, and ask the
Commission to implement additional
measures and criteria to allow for
concrete improvements in RTO
responsiveness.233
173. TAPS also notes that the
Commission failed to implement
specific requirements for RTO
responsiveness or accountability. TAPS
points to the suggestions it made in its
comments to the NOPR, including
requirements for cost-benefit analyses,
annual public reporting of RTO
performance measurements, requiring
RTO management compensation to be
tied to consumer-focused performance
measures, and an improved budget
review process with advance
stakeholder review. TAPS also argued
that RTOs should be held accountable
for fulfilling obligations to plan and
expand the transmission system to meet
230 Order No. 719, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,281
at P 556–57.
231 Id. P 515.
D. Responsiveness of RTOs and ISOs to
Customers and Other Stakeholders
170. In the Final Rule, the
Commission required RTOs and ISOs to
establish a means for customers and
other stakeholders to have a form of
direct access to the board of directors,
and thereby to increase the boards of
directors’ responsiveness to these
entities. The Commission required each
RTO or ISO to submit a compliance
filing demonstrating that it has in place,
or will adopt, practices and procedures
to ensure that its board of directors is
responsive to customers and other
229 Market Monitoring Units in Regional
Transmission Organizations and Independent
System Operators, 111 FERC ¶ 61,267 (2005).
stakeholders. The compliance filings
will be assessed based on four criteria.
The Commission also directed each
RTO and ISO to post on its Web site its
mission statement or organizational
charter.230 Requests for rehearing were
timely filed with respect to: the criteria
for responsiveness, including the
implementation of cost-benefit analyses
by RTOs and ISOs and the inclusion of
board members with State regulatory
experience; the potential for use of
hybrid boards; and the lack of a
mandate for specific items in the RTO
or ISO mission statement.
232 APPA–CMUA at 41 (citing APPA NOPR
Comments at 97–103).
233 Id. at 40–43.
1. Criteria for Responsiveness
171. In the Final Rule, the
Commission adopted four criteria from
the NOPR for assessing the filed
practices and procedures of each RTO
and ISO:
• Inclusiveness—The business
practices and procedures must ensure
that any customer or other stakeholder
affected by the operation of the RTO or
ISO, or its representative, is permitted to
communicate its views to the RTO’s or
ISO’s board of directors.
• Fairness in Balancing Diverse
Interests—The business practices and
procedures must ensure that the
interests of customers or other
stakeholders are equitably considered
and that deliberation and consideration
of RTO and ISO issues are not
dominated by any single stakeholder
category.
• Representation of Minority
Positions—The business practices and
procedures must ensure that, in
instances where stakeholders are not in
total agreement on a particular issue,
minority positions are communicated to
the RTO’s or ISO’s board of directors at
the same time as majority positions.
• Ongoing Responsiveness—The
business practices and procedures must
provide for stakeholder input into the
RTO’s or ISO’s decisions as well as
mechanisms to provide feedback to
stakeholders to ensure that information
exchange and communication continue
over time.
PO 00000
Frm 00024
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
E:\FR\FM\29JYR2.SGM
29JYR2
Federal Register / Vol. 74, No. 144 / Wednesday, July 29, 2009 / Rules and Regulations
customers’ needs. TAPS argues that the
stakeholder process mandated in the
Final Rule will not be sufficient to meet
the needs it outlined in its comments,
and it notes that a recently-released
GAO Report confirms the need for
Commission action and oversight.234
Accordingly, TAPS asks the
Commission to implement its suggested
requirements, or to institute a new
NOPR on this topic.235
174. SMUD also argues that the
Commission should require RTOs and
ISOs to implement performance
penalties for managers. It notes that the
accountability of RTOs for results is
distinct from RTO responsiveness. Since
RTOs and ISOs are not-for-profit
entities, SMUD argues, they cannot be
penalized for imprudence. Accordingly,
the Commission should address the
need for RTOs and ISOs to adopt
performance penalties for imprudent
decisions by managers.236
175. SMUD further argues that the
Commission erred in failing to require
RTOs and ISOs to conduct cost-benefit
analyses before implementing major
initiatives. It believes that such a
requirement would impose discipline
on RTOs and ISOs and improve
accountability to stakeholders. SMUD
also asserts that the Commission must
clarify that, in specific factual
situations, the absence of sector
representation or procedures for
rejecting majority stakeholder positions
would violate the responsiveness
criteria.237
176. Pennsylvania PUC states that the
Commission failed to address its
concerns regarding the control of board
election procedures by RTO or ISO
employees or managers. Pennsylvania
PUC argues that this issue touches on
board ‘‘capture’’ by RTO or ISO
management, and is not sufficiently
addressed by the Final Rule.238
mstockstill on DSKH9S0YB1PROD with RULES2
b. Commission Determination
177. The Commission reviewed the
proposals for new criteria and board
practices in preparing the Final Rule
and found that neither more specific
criteria nor additional criteria from the
Commission were necessary or
appropriate. We deny rehearing on this
issue.
178. The criteria established for
responsiveness were intended to
balance the need to improve RTOs’ and
ISOs’ responsiveness to their
234 TAPS at 67 (citing 2008 GAO Report). See
supra note 129.
235 TAPS at 67.
236 SMUD at 9.
237 Id. at 11.
238 Pennsylvania PUC at 7.
VerDate Nov<24>2008
18:36 Jul 28, 2009
Jkt 217001
stakeholders with the development of
practices that best suit the needs of the
individual RTO or ISO.239 We continue
to believe that this process best works
through collaboration between the RTO
or ISO and its stakeholders based on the
broad principles laid out by the
Commission, rather than through the
Commission mandating specific
outcomes. Further, RTOs and ISOs are
still evolving institutions; they and their
stakeholders may want to add, remove,
or improve specific responsiveness
provisions over time, without being
prevented from doing so by Commission
codification of today’s practices. Many
of the specific criteria suggested in the
comments prior to the Final Rule and in
the requests for rehearing are better
addressed through the stakeholder
process, where RTOs and ISOs can
tailor these ideas to the needs of their
regions, and amend them as needed
without a change in Commission
regulations.
179. In establishing the four criteria
for board responsiveness, the
Commission’s goal was to be sufficiently
prescriptive to give RTOs and ISOs a
guideline for how to structure their
board policies, without being so specific
as to micromanage each RTO’s and
ISO’s policy. For instance, although we
believe that cost-benefit analyses can be
useful in analyzing new projects, we are
unconvinced that the Commission
should mandate cost-benefit analyses in
all circumstances where an RTO or ISO
engages in a major initiative. We do not
have enough evidence in the record to
determine when and how an RTO or
ISO should be required to perform a
cost-benefit analysis. Instead, in the
Final Rule, we encouraged interested
parties to raise this idea with individual
RTOs or ISOs, and allow the RTO or ISO
to work out a policy that is tailored to
its needs.240
180. The specific requirements raised
by APPA, TAPS and others represent
the end point of the policy process, and
should be the result of a dialogue
between RTOs and ISOs and their
stakeholders rather than Commission
mandate. We are interested here in
making sure that stakeholders are able
to have a productive dialogue with their
RTO or ISO, and the criteria the
Commission established in the Final
Rule were designed to require that this
be done in a way determined by each
region.
239 Order No. 719, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,281
at P 505.
240 Id. P 515. See also discussion supra P 71
(declining to require cost-benefit analysis for ARCs’
participation in RTO- and ISO-administered
markets but encouraging RTOs and ISOs to evaluate
this option individually).
PO 00000
Frm 00025
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
37799
181. With respect to Pennsylvania
PUC’s concern regarding the
relationship between the RTO or ISO
board and the entity’s employees, we
note that Pennsylvania PUC has not
presented any evidence that this is a
generic issue for all RTOs and ISOs, and
does not make the case that a
Commission mandate is necessary or
appropriate. Pennsylvania PUC should
raise any concerns regarding specific
RTO or ISO practices during the
stakeholder process for forming the
responsiveness practices and
procedures for that RTO or ISO.
Pennsylvania PUC may raise the issue
again with the Commission following
the RTO and ISO compliance filings if
it believes that its concerns have not
been adequately addressed.
182. Similarly, with respect to
SMUD’s and TAPS’ requests for
requirements for performance penalties
for managers, we continue to encourage,
but not require, that executive
compensation programs give
appropriate weight to responsiveness.
As we discuss further below, the
Commission mandating specific
requirements with respect to board
structure or board and management
compensation could lead to a slippery
slope,241 and may also be outside the
Commission’s jurisdiction.242
2. Hybrid Boards
183. In the Final Rule, the
Commission did not require RTOs or
ISOs to adopt a specific form of board
structure, whether board advisory
committee, hybrid board, or other. The
Commission found that a one-size-fitsall approach was not warranted. The
Commission did note that it viewed the
board advisory committee as a
particularly strong mechanism for
enhancing responsiveness, and that it
expected each RTO and ISO to work
with its stakeholders to develop the
mechanism that best suits its needs.243
184. With respect to hybrid boards,
the Commission followed its ruling in
Order No. 2000,244 in which it noted
that RTOs and ISOs take many different
forms to reflect the various needs of
241 See
infra, note 254.
Cal. Indep. Sys. Operator Corp. v. FERC,
372 F.3d 395 (D.C. Cir. 2004).
243 Order No. 719, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,281
at P 534.
244 Regional Transmission Organizations, Order
No. 2000, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,089 (1999), order
on reh’g, Order No. 2000–A, FERC Stats. & Regs.
¶ 31,092 (2000), aff’d sub nom. Pub. Util. Dist. No.
1 of Snohomish County, Washington v. FERC, 272
F.3d 607 (D.C. Cir. 2001).
242 See
E:\FR\FM\29JYR2.SGM
29JYR2
37800
Federal Register / Vol. 74, No. 144 / Wednesday, July 29, 2009 / Rules and Regulations
each region.245 The Commission denied
requests to disallow hybrid boards in
this proceeding, reasoning that a hybrid
governance structure could be
constructed in a way that allows for the
expertise of various groups to inform the
decision-making process, while still
retaining board independence such that
no individual market participant is
given undue influence over the
decisions of the board. The Commission
noted that commenters were free to raise
objections to the specific hybrid board
proposals made by RTOs and ISOs in
their compliance filings.246
mstockstill on DSKH9S0YB1PROD with RULES2
a. Requests for Rehearing
185. Several parties argue that the
Commission erred in allowing RTOs
and ISOs to choose to create hybrid
boards. For instance, Illinois Commerce
Commission argues that board advisory
committees are a superior method of
promoting responsiveness, and that the
Commission should remove the option
of hybrid boards based on their many
flaws.247 Pennsylvania PUC argues that
allowing hybrid boards would be at
odds with the principle of
independence established by the
Commission in Orders No. 888 248 and
2000. Pennsylvania PUC argues that
hybrid boards are a bad idea for several
reasons, including the difficulty hybrid
board members would have in fulfilling
their fiduciary duties, the potential for
confrontation among members of a
sector, and the inability to protect
confidential information from
disclosure or misuse.249
186. Industrial Coalitions state that
the Commission failed to present
adequate evidence that hybrid boards
could be appropriately independent and
responsive. They argue that an RTO’s or
ISO’s independence depends on the
independence of its board members, and
that a hybrid board would, by
definition, violate this independence
requirement. Additionally, Industrial
Coalitions argue that a hybrid board
structure would expose independent
board members to undue influence from
245 Order No. 719, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,281
at P 537 (citing Order No. 2000, FERC Stats. & Regs.
31,089 at 31,073–75).
246 Id.
247 Illinois Commerce Commission at 9.
248 Promoting Wholesale Competition Through
Open Access Non-Discriminatory Transmission
Services by Public Utilities; Recovery of Stranded
Costs by Public Utilities and Transmitting Utilities,
Order No. 888, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,036 (1996),
order on reh’g, Order No. 888–A, FERC Stats. &
Regs. ¶ 31,048, order on reh’g, Order No. 888–B, 81
FERC ¶ 61,248 (1997), order on reh’g, Order No.
888–C, 82 FERC ¶ 61,046 (1998), aff’d in relevant
part sub nom. Transmission Access Policy Study
Group v. FERC, 225 F.3d 667 (D.C. Cir. 2000), aff’d
sub nom. New York v. FERC, 535 U.S. 1 (2002).
249 Pennsylvania PUC at 9.
VerDate Nov<24>2008
18:36 Jul 28, 2009
Jkt 217001
stakeholder interests on the board,
which could lead to a divisive
atmosphere and suspicion. Finally, they
note that it is unlikely that a hybrid
board would provide adequate
representation to end-use customers,
and would likely actually diminish
customers’ voice.250
187. The Ohio PUC argues that the
Commission erred in not preventing
stakeholders from participating in RTO
or ISO boards, and that this decision
will erode confidence in RTO or ISO
boards because they will be perceived to
be biased and to lack independence.
Both the Ohio PUC and the Wisconsin
PSC also argue that the Commission
erred in not ensuring that States’
interests are adequately represented on
RTO or ISO boards, through seating a
board member with State regulatory
experience.251
b. Commission Determination
188. In the Final Rule, the
Commission did not mandate a specific
form of board structure, but instead
allowed RTOs and ISOs to propose their
own methods of meeting the four
criteria, including through a board
advisory committee or a hybrid
board.252 The Commission heard many
of the same arguments against hybrid
boards made in the requests for
rehearing in comments received prior to
the Final Rule. We are aware that this
is an issue of some controversy, and we
take seriously the potential
independence issues that may arise
from having stakeholder members on an
RTO or ISO board of directors. We
emphasize that the Final Rule did not
repeal any of the requirements for RTO
independence in Order No. 2000 or for
ISO independence in Order No. 888.
However, we are not convinced that it
is impossible to structure a hybrid board
so as both to meet the board
independence requirements of prior
orders and to provide for limited
stakeholder membership without
compromising board independence.
Accordingly, we deny rehearing on this
issue.
189. Our ruling does not imply that
every form of hybrid board would be
acceptable to the Commission. As we
stated in the Final Rule, any board that
includes market participants should be
structured to ensure that no one class
would be allowed to veto a decision
reached by the rest of the board, and
that no two classes could force through
a decision opposed by the rest of the
Coalitions at 17.
PUC at 19; Wisconsin PSC at 3.
252 Order No. 719, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,281
at P 534–37.
PO 00000
250 Industrial
251 Ohio
Frm 00026
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
board.253 We continue to view the board
advisory committee as a particularly
strong mechanism for enhancing
responsiveness, and we will closely
review any RTO or ISO proposal to
ensure that it is just and reasonable and
the result of a thorough stakeholder
process.
190. We also deny the requests to
require that RTO and ISO boards
include one member with State
regulatory experience. While we believe
that a variety of backgrounds and
experiences may be useful for an RTO
or ISO board, we do not see a reason for
the Commission to set generic board
membership requirements for all RTOs
and ISOs regarding any particular
specific experience or qualification. The
Ohio Commission and the Wisconsin
PSC have not convinced us, in their
requests for rehearing, that mandating
State regulatory membership would be
suited to all circumstances, and
therefore we prefer to allow RTOs and
ISOs the flexibility to propose for
Commission approval their own choices
regarding board membership.254 As
previously stated, we will evaluate
those proposals in light of the four
responsiveness criteria enumerated
above.
3. Mission Statements
191. The Final Rule required each
RTO and ISO to post on its Web site a
mission statement or organizational
charter. The Commission encouraged
each RTO and ISO to include in its
mission statement, among other things,
the organization’s purpose, guiding
principles, and commitment to
responsiveness to customers and other
stakeholders, and ultimately to the
consumers who benefit from and pay for
electricity services.255
a. Requests for Rehearing
192. Both APPA and TAPS argue that
the Commission erred in failing to
mandate specific statements in the
proposed mission statement posted by
the RTO or ISO. APPA notes that the
FPA requires that rates be just and
reasonable, and thus RTO and ISO
mission statements should include
explicit language requiring RTOs and
253 Id.
P 537.
some state regulators may be
prohibited by state law from serving on the boards
of public utilities, and an RTO or ISO covering one
state or a small number of states may be unable to
meet such a generic membership requirement. We
further note that requiring that any particular class
of stakeholders, including state regulators, have
membership on RTO and ISO boards is a slippery
slope; we do not wish to impose any affirmative
requirements for category of board members.
255 Order No. 719, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,281
at P 556.
254 Indeed,
E:\FR\FM\29JYR2.SGM
29JYR2
Federal Register / Vol. 74, No. 144 / Wednesday, July 29, 2009 / Rules and Regulations
ISOs to provide cost reductions and net
benefits to the ultimate consumers they
serve.256 TAPS agrees that the required
mission statement should be specific
and consumer-focused. TAPS argues
that the Commission will not fulfill its
obligation under the Federal Power Act
unless it redefines the RTOs’ and ISOs’
mission to include provision of reliable
service at the lowest possible reasonable
rates, and requires RTOs and ISOs to
meet these goals.257
mstockstill on DSKH9S0YB1PROD with RULES2
b. Commission Determination
193. We deny rehearing of the
Commission’s decision not to mandate
specific statements in the mission
statements required of each RTO and
ISO. We find, however, that a successful
mission statement should explain the
mission of an RTO or ISO, as developed
in a collaborative process with
stakeholders, and we do not wish to
interfere with this process by mandating
specific elements of the mission
statement. Indeed, an RTO’s or ISO’s
mission may evolve over time, and it
should be able to update its mission
statements to reflect new mission
elements. (We note in this regard, as
discussed elsewhere in this order, that
some petitioners would have us
reconsider now the existing mission of
some RTOs and ISOs.) If parties believe
that an RTO or ISO mission statement
is not sufficiently consumer-focused, or
is otherwise deficient, they should raise
those objections during the stakeholder
process or in response to the RTO or
ISO compliance filing.
III. Document Availability
194. In addition to publishing the full
text of this document in the Federal
Register, the Commission provides all
interested persons an opportunity to
view and/or print the contents of this
document via the Internet through
FERC’s Home Page (https://www.ferc.gov)
and in FERC’s Public Reference Room
during normal business hours (8:30 a.m.
to 5 p.m. Eastern time) at 888 First
Street, NE., Room 2A, Washington, DC
20426.
195. From FERC’s Home Page on the
Internet, this information is available on
eLibrary. The full text of this document
is available on eLibrary in PDF and
Microsoft Word format for viewing,
printing, and/or downloading. To access
this document in eLibrary, type the
docket number excluding the last three
digits of this document in the docket
number field.
256 APPA
257 TAPS
at 44–45.
at 60–62.
VerDate Nov<24>2008
18:36 Jul 28, 2009
Jkt 217001
196. User assistance is available for
eLibrary and the FERC’s Web site during
normal business hours from FERC
Online Support at 202–502–6652 (toll
free at 1–866–208–3676) or e-mail at
ferconlinesupport@ferc.gov, or the
Public Reference Room at (202) 502–
8371, TTY (202) 502–8659. E-mail the
Public Reference Room at
public.referenceroom@ferc.gov.
IV. Effective Date
197. Changes to Order No. 719 made
in this order on rehearing will be
effective on August 28, 2009.
List of Subjects in 18 CFR Part 35
Electric power rates, Electric utilities,
Reporting and recordkeeping
requirements.
By the Commission. Commissioner Kelly is
concurring in part and dissenting in part
with a separate statement attached.
Nathaniel J. Davis, Sr.,
Deputy Secretary.
In consideration of the foregoing, the
Commission amends part 35, Chapter I,
Title 18, of the Code of Federal
Regulations, as follows:
■
PART 35—FILING OF RATE
SCHEDULES AND TARIFFS
1. The authority citation for part 35
continues to read as follows:
■
Authority: 16 U.S.C. 791a–825r, 2601–
2645; 31 U.S.C. 9701; 42 U.S.C. 7101–7352.
2. In § 35.28, paragraph (g)(1)(iii) is
revised as follows:
■
§ 35.28 Non-discriminatory open access
transmission tariff.
*
*
*
*
*
(g) * * *
(1) * * *
(iii) Aggregation of retail customers.
Each Commission-approved
independent system operator and
regional transmission organization must
accept bids from an aggregator of retail
customers that aggregates the demand
response of the customers of utilities
that distributed more than 4 million
megawatt-hours in the previous fiscal
year, and the customers of utilities that
distributed 4 million megawatt-hours or
less in the previous fiscal year, where
the relevant electric retail regulatory
authority permits such customers’
demand response to be bid into
organized markets by an aggregator of
retail customers. An independent
system operator or regional transmission
organization must not accept bids from
an aggregator of retail customers that
aggregates the demand response of the
PO 00000
Frm 00027
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
37801
customers of utilities that distributed
more than 4 million megawatt-hours in
the previous fiscal year, where the
relevant electric retail regulatory
authority prohibits such customers’
demand response to be bid into
organized markets by an aggregator of
retail customers, or the customers of
utilities that distributed 4 million
megawatt-hours or less in the previous
fiscal year, unless the relevant electric
retail regulatory authority permits such
customers’ demand response to be bid
into organized markets by an aggregator
of retail customers.
*
*
*
*
*
Note: The following statement will not
appear in the Code of Federal Regulations.
KELLY, Commissioner, concurring in
part and dissenting in part:
As I have noted in my separate
statements at each phase of this
proceeding, I continue to have
misgivings about the potential impacts
of several of Order No. 719’s directives,
including (1) the scarcity pricing
measures; (2) the issue of promoting
responsiveness of RTOs/ISOs by
allowing them to adopt hybrid boards
with stakeholder members; and (3)
MMUs being removed from tariff
administration and mitigation.1 Despite
my ongoing concerns, I believe that
some of these proposals have positively
evolved over the course of this
proceeding. A good deal of that
evolution is due to the commenters who
have taken the time to participate in our
process, thereby moving the debate in a
positive direction. I also want to
commend Commission staff who have
worked tirelessly on these efforts. I
believe that the Commission has
appropriately used Order No. 719 as a
vehicle to move the issue of competition
in organized markets in a generally
positive direction. Further, as the order
states, the Commission will continue to
look for ways to strengthen organized
markets.
Accordingly, I respectfully concur in
part and dissent in part.
Suedeen G. Kelly
[FR Doc. E9–17364 Filed 7–28–09; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6717–01–P
1 See Wholesale Competition in Regions with
Organized Electric Markets, Advance Notice of
Proposed Rulemaking, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 32,617
(2007), Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, FERC Stats.
& Regs. ¶ 32,628 (2008), Order No. 719, 73 FR
61,400 (Oct. 28, 2008), FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,281
(2008) (Comm’r Kelly concurring in part and
dissenting in part).
E:\FR\FM\29JYR2.SGM
29JYR2
Agencies
[Federal Register Volume 74, Number 144 (Wednesday, July 29, 2009)]
[Rules and Regulations]
[Pages 37776-37801]
From the Federal Register Online via the Government Printing Office [www.gpo.gov]
[FR Doc No: E9-17364]
[[Page 37775]]
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
Part II
Department of Energy
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
18 CFR Part 35
Wholesale Competition in Regions With Organized Electric Markets; Final
Rule
Federal Register / Vol. 74, No. 144 / Wednesday, July 29, 2009 /
Rules and Regulations
[[Page 37776]]
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
DEPARTMENT OF ENERGY
Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
18 CFR Part 35
[Docket No. RM07-19-001; Order No. 719-A]
Wholesale Competition in Regions With Organized Electric Markets
July 16, 2009.
AGENCY: Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, DOE.
ACTION: Final rule; order on rehearing.
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
SUMMARY: In this order on rehearing, the Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission (Commission) affirms its basic determinations in Order No.
719, Wholesale Competition in Regions with Organized Electric Markets,
which amended Commission regulations to improve the operation of
organized wholesale electric markets in four areas: Demand response,
including pricing during periods of operating reserve shortage; long-
term power contracting; market-monitoring policies; and the
responsiveness of RTOs and ISOs to their customers and other
stakeholders. This order denies in part and grants in part rehearing
and clarification regarding certain provisions of Order No. 719.
DATES: Effective Date: This is effective on August 28, 2009.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
Russell Profozich (Technical Information), Office of Energy Market
Regulation, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, 888 First Street,
NE., Washington, DC 20426. Russell.Profozich@ferc.gov. (202) 502-6478.
Tina Ham (Legal Information), Office of the General Counsel, Federal
Energy Regulatory Commission, 888 First Street, NE., Washington, DC
20426. Tina.Ham@ferc.gov. (202) 502-6224.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION:
Table of Contents
Paragraph
numbers
I. Introduction............................................ 1
A. Summary of Order No. 719............................ 2
B. Requests for Rehearing.............................. 10
II. Discussion............................................. 13
A. Demand Response and Pricing During Periods of 13
Operating Reserve Shortages in Organized Markets......
1. Ancillary Services Provided by Demand Response 13
Providers.........................................
a. Request for Rehearing....................... 15
b. Commission Determination.................... 16
2. Aggregation of Retail Customers................. 17
a. Requests for Rehearing...................... 18
b. Commission Determination.................... 41
3. Market Rules Governing Price Formation During 72
Periods of Operating Reserve Shortage.............
a. Requests for Rehearing...................... 74
b. Commission Determination.................... 93
B. Long-Term Power Contracting in Organized Markets.... 107
1. Hedging Instruments............................. 108
a. Request for Rehearing....................... 109
b. Commission Determination.................... 110
2. Structural Issues............................... 111
a. Request for Rehearing....................... 112
b. Commission Determination.................... 117
C. Market-Monitoring Policies.......................... 123
1. Market Mitigation............................... 127
a. Requests for Rehearing...................... 129
b. Commission Determination.................... 133
2. Relationship Between Internal and External MMU.. 138
a. Requests for Rehearing...................... 139
b. Commission Determination.................... 141
3. State Access to MMU Information................. 144
a. Requests for Rehearing...................... 145
b. Commission Determination.................... 146
4. Offer and Bid Data.............................. 151
a. Requests for Rehearing or Clarification..... 152
b. Commission Determination.................... 156
5. Ethics Provisions............................... 160
a. Request for Rehearing or Clarification...... 161
b. Commission Determination.................... 164
6. Referral of Market Design Flaws................. 167
D. Responsiveness of RTOs and ISOs to Customers and 171
Other Stakeholders....................................
1. Criteria for Responsiveness..................... 172
a. Requests for Rehearing...................... 173
b. Commission Determination.................... 178
2. Hybrid Boards................................... 184
a. Requests for Rehearing...................... 186
b. Commission Determination.................... 189
3. Mission Statements.............................. 192
a. Requests for Rehearing...................... 193
b. Commission Determination.................... 194
III. Document Availability................................. 195
IV. Effective Date......................................... 198
Regulatory Text
[[Page 37777]]
128 FERC ] 61,059
Before Commissioners: Jon Wellinghoff, Chairman; Suedeen G. Kelly,
Marc Spitzer, and Philip D. Moeller.
I. Introduction
1. On October 17, 2008, the Commission issued a Final Rule \1\
establishing reforms to improve the operation of organized wholesale
electric power markets \2\ and amended its regulations under the
Federal Power Act (FPA) in the areas of: (1) Demand response, including
pricing during periods of operating reserve shortage; (2) long-term
power contracting; (3) market-monitoring policies; and (4) the
responsiveness of RTOs and ISOs to their customers and other
stakeholders.\3\ The Commission stated that these reforms are intended
to improve wholesale competition to protect consumers in several ways:
By providing more supply options, encouraging new entry and innovation,
spurring deployment of new technologies, removing barriers to
comparable treatment of demand response, improving operating
performance, exerting downward pressure on costs, and shifting risk
away from consumers.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1\ Wholesale Competition in Regions with Organized Electric
Markets, Order No. 719, 73 FR 64,100 (Oct. 28, 2008), FERC Stats. &
Regs. ] 31,281 (2008) (Order No. 719 or Final Rule).
\2\ Organized market regions are areas of the country in which a
regional transmission organization (RTO) or independent system
operator (ISO) operates day-ahead and/or real-time energy markets.
The following Commission-approved RTOs and ISOs have organized
markets: PJM Interconnection, LLC (PJM); New York Independent System
Operator, Inc. (NYISO); Midwest Independent Transmission System
Operator, Inc. (Midwest ISO); ISO New England, Inc. (ISO New
England); California Independent System Operator Corp. (CAISO); and
Southwest Power Pool, Inc. (SPP).
\3\ In this rulemaking, the Commission also issued an advanced
notice of proposed rulemaking, Wholesale Competition in Regions with
Organized Electric Markets, Advance Notice of Proposed Rulemaking,
FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 32,617 (2007) (ANOPR) and a notice of proposed
rulemaking, Wholesale Competition in Regions with Organized Electric
Markets, Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 32,628
(2008) (NOPR).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
A. Summary of Order No. 719
2. In the area of demand response, the Commission required each RTO
and ISO to: (1) Accept bids from demand response resources in RTOs' and
ISOs' markets for certain ancillary services on a basis comparable to
other resources; (2) eliminate, during a system emergency, a charge to
a buyer that takes less electric energy in the real-time market than it
purchased in the day-ahead market; (3) in certain circumstances, permit
an aggregator of retail customers (ARC) to bid demand response on
behalf of retail customers directly into the organized energy market;
and (4) modify their market rules, as necessary, to allow the market-
clearing price, during periods of operating reserve shortage, to reach
a level that rebalances supply and demand so as to maintain reliability
while providing sufficient provisions for mitigating market power.\4\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\4\ Order No. 719, FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 31,281 at P 4, 15.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
3. Additionally, the Commission recognized that further reforms may
be necessary to eliminate barriers to demand response in the future. To
that end, the Commission required each RTO or ISO to assess and report
on any remaining barriers to comparable treatment of demand response
resources that are within the Commission's jurisdiction. The Commission
further required each RTO's or ISO's Independent Market Monitor to
submit a report describing its views on its RTO's or ISO's assessment
to the Commission.\5\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\5\ Id. P 274.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
4. With regard to long-term power contracting, the Commission
required each RTO and ISO to dedicate a portion of its Web sites for
market participants to post offers to buy or sell power on a long-term
basis.
5. To improve market monitoring, the Commission required each RTO
and ISO to provide its Market Monitoring Unit (MMU) with access to
market data, resources and personnel sufficient to carry out their
duties, and required the MMU to report directly to the RTO or ISO board
of directors.\6\ In addition, the Commission required that the MMU's
functions include: (1) Identifying ineffective market rules and
recommending proposed rules and tariff changes; (2) reviewing and
reporting on the performance of the wholesale markets to the RTO or
ISO, the Commission, and other interested entities; and (3) notifying
appropriate Commission staff of instances in which a market
participant's or the RTO's or ISO's behavior may require investigation.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\6\ The use of the phrase ``board of directors'' herein also
includes the board of managers, board of governors, and similar
entities. An internal MMU in a hybrid structure may report to
management so long as it does not perform any of the core MMU
functions.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
6. The Commission also took the following actions with regard to
MMUs: (1) Expanded the list of recipients of MMU recommendations
regarding rule and tariff changes, and broadened the scope of behavior
to be reported to the Commission; (2) modified MMU participation in
tariff administration and market mitigation, required each RTO and ISO
to include ethics standards for MMU employees in its tariff, and
required each RTO and ISO to consolidate all its MMU provisions in one
section of its tariff; and (3) expanded the dissemination of MMU market
information to a broader constituency, with reports made on a more
frequent basis than in the past, and reduced the time period before
energy market bid and offer data are released to the public.
7. Finally, the Commission established an obligation for each RTO
and ISO to establish a means for customers and other stakeholders to
have a form of direct access to the RTO or ISO board of directors, and
thereby, increase its responsiveness to customers and other
stakeholders. The Commission stated that it will assess each RTO's or
ISO's compliance filing using four responsiveness criteria: (1)
Inclusiveness; (2) fairness in balancing diverse interests; (3)
representation of minority positions; and (4) ongoing responsiveness.
8. The Commission stated in the Final Rule that its actions in
these four areas are consistent with its duty to improve the operation
of wholesale power markets.\7\ The Commission also reiterated its
statement from the underlying Notice of Proposed Rulemaking that the
reforms addressed in this proceeding do not represent the Commission's
final effort to improve the functioning of competitive markets for the
benefit of consumers. Rather, the Commission will continue to evaluate
other specific reforms that may strengthen organized markets.\8\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\7\ Order No. 719, FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 31,281 at P 2.
\8\ Id. P 14.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
9. In each of the four areas, the Final Rule required each RTO or
ISO to consult with its stakeholders and make a compliance filing that
explains how its existing practices comply with the Final Rule's
reforms, or its plans to attain compliance.\9\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\9\ Id. P 8, 578-83.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
B. Requests for Rehearing
10. The following entities have filed timely requests for rehearing
or for clarification of Order No. 719: American Electric Power
Corporation (AEP); American Public Power Association (APPA) and
California Municipal Utilities Association (CMUA) (jointly, APPA-CMUA);
APPA, CMUA and National Rural Electric Cooperative Association (NRECA)
(collectively, Joint Petitioners); Illinois Commerce
[[Page 37778]]
Commission; Coalition of Midwest Transmission Customers, NEPOOL
Industrial Customer Coalition, and PJM Industrial Customers Coalition
(collectively, Industrial Coalitions); Minnesota Public Utilities
Commission (Minnesota PUC); National Association of Regulatory Utility
Commissioners (NARUC); Public Utilities Commission of Ohio (Ohio PUC);
Old Dominion Electric Cooperative (Old Dominion); Potomac Economics,
Ltd. (Potomac Economics); Pennsylvania Public Utilities Commission
(Pennsylvania PUC); Sacramento Municipal Utility District (SMUD);
Transmission Access Policy Study Group (TAPS); and Public Service
Commission of Wisconsin (Wisconsin PSC). New York Independent System
Operator, Inc. (NYISO) submitted an untimely request for clarification.
Additionally, PJM Interconnection, L.L.C. filed a motion for leave to
respond and response to the requests for rehearing. Joint Petitioners
filed an answer to PJM's motion.\10\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\10\ Additionally, Monitoring Analytics, LLC filed an out-of-
time motion to intervene in this proceeding, but did not seek
rehearing.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
11. We dismiss NYISO's untimely request for clarification of Order
No. 719 because it is, in essence, an untimely request for rehearing.
The courts have repeatedly recognized that the time period within which
a party may file a petition for rehearing of a Commission order is
statutorily established at 30 days by section 313(a) of the FPA\11\ and
that the Commission has no discretion to extend that deadline.\12\
Accordingly, the Commission has long held that it lacks the authority
to consider requests for rehearing filed more than 30 days after
issuance of a Commission order.\13\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\11\ 16 U.S.C 825l.
\12\ See, e.g., City of Campbell v. FERC, 770 F.2d 1180, 1183
(D.C. Cir. 1985) (``The 30-day time requirement of [the FPA] is as
much a part of the jurisdictional threshold as the mandate to file
for a rehearing.''); Boston Gas Co. v. FERC, 575 F.2d 975, 977-98,
979 (1st Cir. 1978) (describing identical rehearing provision of the
Natural Gas Act as ``a tightly structured and formal provision.
Neither the Commission nor the courts are given any form of
jurisdictional discretion.'').
\13\ See, e.g., Arkansas Power & Light Co., 19 FERC ] 61,115 at
61,217-18, reh'g denied, 20 FERC ] 61,013, at 61,034 (1982). See
also Public Serv. Co. of New Hampshire, 56 FERC ] 61,105, at 61,403
(1991); CMS Midland, Inc., 56 FERC ] 61,177, at 61,623 (1991).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
12. Rule 713(d)(1) of the Commission's Rules of Practice and
Procedure, 18 CFR 385.713(d)(1) (2008), prohibits answers to requests
for rehearing. Accordingly, we reject PJM's motion to respond to
requests for rehearing and Joint Petitioners' answer to PJM's motion.
II. Discussion
A. Demand Response and Pricing During Periods of Operating Reserve
Shortages in Organized Markets
1. Ancillary Services Provided by Demand Response Providers
13. The Final Rule required each RTO or ISO to accept bids from
demand response resources, on a basis comparable to any other
resources, for ancillary services that are acquired in a competitive
bidding process, if the demand response resources: (1) Are technically
capable of providing the ancillary service and meet the necessary
technical requirements; and (2) submit a bid under the generally-
applicable bidding rules at or below the market-clearing price, unless
the laws or regulations of the relevant electric retail regulatory
authority do not permit a retail customer to participate. All accepted
bids would receive the market-clearing price.\14\ The Commission
determined that these requirements would remove barriers to the
comparable treatment of demand-side and supply-side resources.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\14\ Order No. 719, FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 31,281 at P 47.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
14. In the Final Rule, in response to commenters who asked the
Commission to allow energy efficiency resources to bid into the
organized markets, the Commission recognized the value of energy
efficiency resources. The Commission stated that it has not excluded
from eligibility as a provider of ancillary services any type of
resource that is technically capable of providing the ancillary
service, including energy efficiency resources. However, because this
proceeding did not propose to include energy efficiency resources as
providers of competitively procured ancillary services, the Commission
stated that it did not have an adequate record to address this
issue.\15\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\15\ Id. P 56.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
a. Request for Rehearing
15. Pennsylvania PUC asserts that the Commission should uphold its
``comparable terms and conditions'' principle regarding acceptance of
demand response resources for ancillary services by requiring each RTO
and ISO to file tariff provisions defining energy efficiency resources
as resources qualified to bid into energy markets and ancillary
services markets upon such terms and conditions as the RTO or ISO may
propose. In addition, it asks the Commission to require each RTO and
ISO to supply arguments and adequate record evidence in support of such
a filing so that the Commission can determine whether energy efficiency
resources are being accepted on a comparable basis with any other
resources qualified to bid into energy markets and ancillary services
markets.\16\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\16\ Pennsylvania PUC at 4.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
b. Commission Determination
16. The Final Rule does not exclude from eligibility any type of
resource that is technically capable of providing an ancillary service,
and therefore we disagree with Pennsylvania PUC that the Final Rule
leaves in place a barrier to the use of energy efficiency resources
that we must remedy on rehearing. An RTO or ISO is free to work with
its stakeholders and incorporate energy efficiency resources into its
markets on a basis that is appropriate for its region.\17\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\17\ Order No. 719, FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 31,281 at P 276.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
2. Aggregation of Retail Customers
17. Order No. 719 required RTOs and ISOs to amend their market
rules as necessary to permit an ARC to bid demand response on behalf of
retail customers directly into the RTO's or ISO's organized markets,
unless the laws or regulations of the relevant electric retail
regulatory authority do not permit a retail customer to participate.
The Commission determined that allowing an ARC to act as an
intermediary for many small retail loads that cannot individually
participate in the organized market would reduce a barrier to demand
response.\18\ The Commission directed RTOs and ISOs to submit
compliance filings to propose amendments to their tariffs or otherwise
demonstrate how their existing tariffs and market rules comply with the
Final Rule.\19\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\18\ Id. P 154.
\19\ Id. P 163.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
a. Requests for Rehearing
i. Commission Jurisdiction
18. Several petitioners assert that the Final Rule's ARC
requirements exceed the Commission's statutory authority under the
FPA.\20\ TAPS and Joint Petitioners state that under section 201(a) of
the FPA, the Commission's jurisdiction is limited to the transmission
of electric energy in interstate commerce and the sale of such energy
at wholesale in interstate
[[Page 37779]]
commerce.\21\ They argue that a retail customer's reduction of energy
consumption is neither a wholesale sale of electric energy nor
transmission in interstate commerce, and that retail sales are sales of
electric energy to end users that are not sales for resale.\22\ Joint
Petitioners add that a promise not to consume electric energy at a
particular time is a product not covered by the plain language of the
FPA.\23\\\ TAPS, therefore, concludes that the Commission lacks
jurisdiction to modify retail electricity sales by effectively
establishing a new rule that authorizes retail customers purchasing
electricity (or non-consumption) to resell that electricity into
wholesale markets, either directly or through a third party.\24\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\20\ See, e.g., TAPS at 9-13; Joint Petitioners at 18-23; NARUC
at 3. NARUC states that it incorporates by reference the arguments
presented on this issue by Joint Petitioners' request for rehearing.
NARUC at 5.
\21\ 16 U.S.C. 824(a).
\22\ TAPS at 11-12; Joint Petitioners at 18-19 (citing United
States v. Public Utils. Comm'n of California, 345 U.S. 295, 303
(1953); Federal Power Comm'n v. Southern California Edison Co., 376
U.S. 202, 216 (1964)).
\23\ Joint Petitioners at 19.
\24\ TAPS at 12-13 (citing N.Y. v. FERC, 535 U.S. 1, 20 (2002);
FPC v. Conway Corp., 426 U.S. 271, 276-77 (1976)).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
19. Joint Petitioners argue that the Final Rule's ARC requirement
violates the separation of Federal and State jurisdiction because it
effectively requires public power systems and cooperatives to take
affirmative action to consider retail aggregation issues.\25\ Joint
Petitioners state that the majority of these systems do not have laws
or regulations addressing end-use customer aggregation. They argue that
the Commission has no jurisdiction to require such affirmative action
because it is beyond the scope of its legal authority set out in the
FPA.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\25\ Joint Petitioners at 13, 18 (citing Northern States Power
Co., 176 F.3d 1090, 1096 (8th Cir. 1999), reh'g en banc denied 1999
U.S. App. LEXIS 23493 (8th Cir. Sept. 1, 1999), cert. denied sub
nom.; Enron Power Mktg., Inc. v. Northern States Power Co., 528 U.S.
1182 (2000); Atlantic City Electric Co. v. FERC, 295 F.3d 1, 8 (D.C.
Cir. 2002)).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
20. Additionally, TAPS argues that States' and relevant electric
retail regulatory authorities' laws and regulations do not grant retail
customers either the title or a contract right to resell retail
electricity (or any such non-consumption). In that respect, TAPS argues
that the Final Rule intrudes into retail electric service rates by
requiring RTOs and ISOs to accept demand response bids that may be
prohibited by State law, without first obtaining confirmation that such
transactions are permitted by the relevant electric retail regulatory
authority. Joint Petitioners also note that Congress acknowledged that
State and local regulation extends to such consumption decisions when
it directed State regulators and non-regulated utilities to consider
implementing demand response programs at the State and local level in
2007 amendments to the Public Utility Regulatory Policies Act
(PURPA).\26\ Further, they argue that the Commission failed to explain
how it has jurisdiction over the demand response programs of public
power systems and cooperatives that are not public utilities, and are
therefore exempt, under FPA section 201(f), from the Commission's FPA
section 206 authority \27\ Joint Petitioners contend that the
Commission cannot ``indirectly'' claim jurisdiction over non-
jurisdictional entities.\28\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\26\ Section 532 of the Energy Independence and Security Act of
2007 amended PURPA section 111(d) by adding a new standard that
requires consideration of rate design modifications to promote
energy efficiency investments. 16 U.S.C. 2621(d). To assist in this
effort, Joint Petitioners note that APPA and NRECA commissioned a
reference manual regarding the new requirements. Reference Manual
and Procedures for Implementation of the PURPA Standards in the
Energy Independence and Security Act of 2007, Dr. Ken Rose and
Michael Murphy, available at https://www.naruc.org/Publications/EISAStandardsManualFINAL.pdf. Joint Petitioners argue that efforts
to have distribution cooperatives or public power distribution
systems invest in a demand response program after considering these
new federal PURPA standards could be undermined by the activities of
third-party ARCs seeking to take the demand response of the public
power or cooperative system's retail customers directly to the
wholesale market. Joint Petitioners at 21.
\27\ 16 U.S.C. 824(f). Joint Petitioners at 21 (citing
Bonneville Power Administration, et al. v. FERC, 422 F.3d 908, 915
(9th Cir. 2005).
\28\ Joint Petitioners state that the ``Commission cannot
bootstrap jurisdiction over * * * non-jurisdictional entities simply
by pointing to jurisdiction over their retail customers'' and that
the Commission ``cannot do indirectly what it cannot do directly.''
Joint Petitioners at 21 (citing Richmond Power & Light v. FERC, 574
F.2d 610, 620 (D.C. Cir. 1978); Altamont Gas Transmission Co., et
al. v. FERC, 92 F.3d 1239, 1248 (D.C. Cir. 1996); and Williams Gas
Processing-Gulf Coast Co., L.P. v. FERC, 331 F.3d 1011, 1022 (D.C.
Cir. 2003)).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
21. Ohio PUC argues that third-party aggregation bids should be
subject to State regulatory authority or approval.\29\ While it agrees
that ARCs should be permitted to aggregate smaller loads, it asserts
that retail customers and their representatives should not be
classified as wholesale customers subject to the Commission's
jurisdiction simply because they provide demand response to the
wholesale market. Therefore, Ohio PUC contends that the Final Rule
should have acknowledged that all contracts by third-party ARCs are
subject to State retail jurisdiction and should be subject to State
commission approval prior to providing demand response resources to an
RTO or ISO.\30\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\29\ Ohio PUC at 6-7 (stating that ``it is the prerogative of
each individual state commission to decide to what extent it will
expose its retail customers to the wholesale market, and what, if
any, advanced technology (i.e., smart meters) its retail customers
desire and wish to purchase'').
\30\ Id. at 6. The Wisconsin PSC states that it adopts Ohio
PUC's arguments on this issue. Wisconsin PSC at 2. NARUC states that
it incorporates by reference the arguments presented on this issue
by Ohio PUC's request for rehearing. NARUC at 5.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
22. Joint Petitioners ask the Commission to rule on rehearing that
in the case of public power systems and cooperative utilities, RTOs and
ISOs should not accept ARCs' demand response bids unless a system's
relevant electric retail regulatory authority affirmatively informs the
RTO or ISO that it permits aggregation by third-party ARCs.\31\ They
believe that this approach would allow the Commission to encourage
demand response while still respecting the State and local retail
regulatory authorities. Similarly, TAPS urges the Commission to modify
the opt-out structure of the ARC requirements by changing it to an opt-
in structure to remedy the jurisdictional defect and to avoid undue
burden to small relevant electric retail regulatory authorities.\32\
TAPS argues that such modifications would invite relevant electric
retail regulatory authorities to contact the RTO or ISO to provide the
necessary notification. Joint Petitioners and TAPS state that absent a
notification that permission has been granted, the RTO or ISO should
presume that sales of demand response in RTO or ISO markets are not
permitted.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\31\ Joint Petitioners at 15-16.
\32\ Specifically, TAPS suggests that the Commission modify the
regulatory text to replace: (1) The ``unless'' clause of 18 CFR
35.28(g)(1)(B)(3)(iii) with ``if the relevant electric retail
regulatory authority expressly permits a retail customer to
participate''; and (2) the ``unless'' clause of 18 CFR
35.28(g)(1)(i)(A) with ``if permitted by the laws or regulations of
the relevant electric retail regulatory authority.'' TAPS at 28.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
23. Additionally, TAPS argues that ARCs and other entities bidding
demand response into RTO or ISO markets should be required to certify
that their sales are permitted. It asserts that it would be difficult
for RTOs or ISOs or relevant electric retail regulatory authorities to
identify, independently, whether improper sales or aggregation occur.
It states that entities bidding demand response into the RTO or ISO
wholesale markets are in the best position to identify the specific
retail loads and customers involved and to verify that such bids are
permitted by the relevant electric retail regulatory authority. It
notes that network customers must provide certification to support
designation of network resources.\33\ Similarly, individual retail
[[Page 37780]]
customers and ARCs should be required to certify that their bids and
sales of demand response into wholesale markets are permitted under
applicable law, and submission by such entities of ineligible demand
response bids should be a tariff violation.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\33\ Id. at 31. TAPS notes that under Order No. 890, network
customers must attest, for each network resource identified for
designation, that: (1) The transmission customer owns or has
committed to purchase the designated network resource; and (2) the
designated network resource meets the requirements for designated
network resources. Preventing Undue Discrimination and Preference in
Transmission Service, Order No. 890, FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 31,241,
order on reh'g, Order No. 890-A, FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 31,261
(2007), order on reh'g, Order No. 890-B, 123 FERC ] 61,299 (2008).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
24. Further, AEP notes that the Final Rule permits retail customers
to participate in an RTO's or ISO's demand program unless the laws or
regulations of the relevant electric retail regulatory authority do not
permit a retail customer to participate. It seeks clarification as to
``whether this exception applies to [s]tate commission-approved tariff
provisions that prohibit sales for resale.'' \34\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\34\ AEP at 1.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
25. AEP asserts that a State commission in a non-retail choice
State should have the opportunity to fully consider and determine
whether an RTO or ISO wholesale demand response program is appropriate
for that State. AEP is concerned that RTOs and ISOs may interpret the
Final Rule's language on the ARC requirement to mean that RTOs and ISOs
may proceed with demand response programs in States where retail
customers are provided with State regulated average embedded cost
rates, unless States specifically opt out of an RTO's or ISO's
wholesale demand response program. AEP argues that such an
interpretation would allow: (1) Non-choice retail customers with
average embedded cost rates an opportunity to arbitrage their load
through sales into wholesale markets to the detriment of remaining
retail customers in that State; and (2) an RTO or ISO to set new policy
without any consideration of unintended consequences to retail
customers.\35\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\35\ Id. at 2.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
26. Additionally, AEP notes that a retail customer's action could
be considered a ``resale'' when the customer purchases electric service
under a retail tariff and then receives compensation for bidding its
load into the wholesale market through a demand response program.
Therefore, AEP asks that the Commission either clarify the Final Rule
to provide that participation in wholesale demand response programs by
retail customers does not constitute a ``sale for resale,'' or require
that retail customers seeking to participate in such programs seek such
an exception from the applicable State commission.\36\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\36\ Id. at 2-3.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
ii. Burden on Small Entities and Regulatory Flexibility Analysis
27. Several petitioners state that requiring the relevant electric
retail regulatory authorities of each public system to consider some
type of affirmative action on the ARC issue imposes a significant
burden on them.\37\ For example, TAPS argues that the Final Rule
requires every relevant electric retail regulatory authority,
regardless of size, to address whether demand response sales may be bid
into an RTO or ISO market and whether ARCs may aggregate demand
response within the regulatory authority's jurisdiction.\38\ Joint
Petitioners argue that, for the majority of retail regulatory
authorities, this would be a substantial undertaking requiring a huge
learning curve to become familiar with the process and consequently
resulting in a lengthy legislative process.\39\ Similarly, TAPS asserts
that it is a huge undertaking for the city council of every municipal
electric system in an RTO or ISO to expressly address this issue
through legislation or regulation.\40\ TAPS adds that the Final Rule
effectively leaves enforcement responsibility with the relevant
electric retail regulatory authority by requiring these entities to
monitor and challenge any bids and certifications by ARCs that are not
permitted within their jurisdiction.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\37\ NARUC states that it incorporates by reference the
arguments presented on this issue by Joint Petitioners' request for
rehearing. NARUC at 5.
\38\ TAPS at 25-26.
\39\ For example, Joint Petitioners note that CMUA explained in
its NOPR comments that the presumption of implicit authority to
allow ARCs to aggregate bids makes no sense in California because
direct access was suspended following the 2000-01 market crisis.
Accordingly, California no longer has laws or regulations dealing
with new direct access, and CMUA has not restructured its retail
rules and ordinances with retail choice as an option. Therefore,
Joint Petitioners state that to now require an affirmative action
would be a substantial undertaking. Joint Petitioners at 16-17.
\40\ TAPS notes that its members include: (1) AMP-Ohio, serving
123 municipal electric systems in Midwest ISO and PJM; (2) Indiana
Municipal Power Agency, serving 51 municipal electric systems in
Midwest ISO and PJM; and (3) Wisconsin Public Power, serving 50
municipal electric systems in Midwest ISO. TAPS at 26.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
28. Joint Petitioners argue that the Commission erred in certifying
that Order No. 719 will not have a significant economic impact on a
substantial number of small entities and certifying that the Final Rule
complies with the Regulatory Flexibility Act of 1980 (RFA).\41\ Joint
Petitioners assert that the reasoning underlying this certification is
invalid and therefore seek rehearing.\42\ They emphasize that, unless
public power systems and cooperatives take affirmative action to enact
the necessary law or regulation, relevant electric retail authorities
could risk having their public power systems' demand response programs
undermined and day-to-day system operations disrupted by ARCs' demand
response activities. They reiterate that it would be a significant
burden for relevant electric retail regulatory authorities of over
1,300 public power systems and 850 distribution cooperatives to take up
this issue. Accordingly, Joint Petitioners maintain that the Final
Rule's ARC requirement would result in a significant adverse impact on
a substantial number of small entities and, therefore, the Commission
is required to provide a certification under the RFA.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\41\ 5 U.S.C. 601-12.
\42\ Joint Petitioners at 23.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
29. TAPS also argues that by imposing responsibilities on small
entities, the Final Rule ignores the RFA's requirements.\43\ TAPS
disputes the Commission's cite to American Trucking Associations, Inc.
v. EPA (American Trucking Associations) \44\ to support its position in
the Final Rule that the RFA analysis is not required. It contends that,
in that case, the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) was not
required to conduct an RFA analysis because whether the small entities
at issue would be burdened by the EPA's action depended on the
intermediate, discretionary action of the States. Under Order No. 719,
however, TAPS asserts that the RTOs and ISOs have no such discretion to
mitigate the impact of the Final Rule's requirements.\45\ TAPS further
contends that American Trucking Associations does not relieve the
Commission of its obligations under the RFA. Therefore, it suggests
that the Commission modify the ARC requirement as stated above, to
ensure that any relevant electric retail regulatory authority that
wishes to allow third-party demand response aggregation could do so,
without unduly
[[Page 37781]]
burdening hundreds of municipal entities.\46\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\43\ TAPS at 26-27.
\44\ American Trucking Ass'ns v. EPA, 175 F.3d 1027, 1044 (DC
Cir. 1999), aff'd in part and rev'd in part sub nom. Whitman v.
American Trucking Ass'ns, 531 U.S. 457 (2001).
\45\ TAPS at 28. TAPS states that the Final Rule ``requires
[load-serving entities] to either: (1) Invest in the legislative
and/or regulatory procedures necessary to obtain an explicit `out'
and enforce it; * * * or (2) undertake the implementation burdens
necessary to accommodate ARCs and retail customers directly bidding
retail demand response into wholesale markets.'' Id.
\46\ Id. at 29.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
30. Joint Petitioners argue that the Commission erred in
arbitrarily and capriciously refusing to consider APPA's compromise
proposal regarding third-party aggregation.\47\ For entities below the
RFA size requirement for small utilities, the RTO or ISO would be
required to assume that ARC aggregation is not permitted unless the
relevant electric retail regulatory authority of such public power
system informed the RTO or ISO that it has elected to allow such
aggregation. Joint Petitioners note that APPA argued in its NOPR
comments that this size-differentiated regime would appropriately
balance the Commission's interest in permitting demand-side
participation in organized wholesale markets without the undue burden
that the Final Rule places on small power systems. Joint Petitioners
argue that Order No. 719 noted, but did not address, APPA's compromise
proposal.\48\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\47\ Joint Petitioners at 27. In its NOPR comments, APPA
suggested an alternative approach of differentiating public power
systems by their size. Under this alternative, the relevant electric
retail regulatory authorities governing public power systems that
are located in the RTO or ISO regions and larger than the RFA size
requirement (i.e., 4 million MWh or more in total output in one
year) would have to consider the issue of third-party ARCs and
aggregation of their retail customers, if they had not already done
so. They would have the affirmative requirement to inform their RTO
or ISO whether their local election was not to permit the
aggregation by ARCs on their public power systems, or permit it only
under enumerated conditions in order to preclude third-party bidding
of their consumers' loads. APPA NOPR Comments at 47-48.
\48\ Joint Petitioners at 28-29.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
31. Similarly, TAPS asserts that, at a minimum, any affirmative
regulatory action requirement should be restricted to systems that are
larger than the RFA threshold of 4 million MWh. An alternative
threshold, according to TAPS, would be ``those municipals with retail
sales of more than 500 million kWh, as used in the PURPA.'' \49\ TAPS
contends that limiting the application of the Final Rule's requirements
in this manner would minimize the burden on small systems associated
with either implementation of the Final Rule or compliance with its
express prohibition requirement, consistent with the Final Rule's RFA
certification.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\49\ TAPS at 30.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
iii. Effect on Existing Demand Response Programs and on Rates,
Metering, and Billing Protocols
32. TAPS argues on rehearing that the Commission failed to: (1)
Adequately address the Final Rule's impact on existing demand response
programs; and (2) provide sufficient evidence to justify the
disruptions to wholesale and retail service that will be created by
authorizing retail customers to sell their demand response in wholesale
markets.
33. According to TAPS, it requested in its NOPR comments that the
Commission take steps not to undermine the existing tariff and
contractual arrangements between load-serving entities and their
customers for demand response programs.\50\ Yet, TAPS asserts, the
Commission imposed new requirements without first independently
assessing the Final Rule's impact on existing load-serving-entity-
administered demand response programs. It asks the Commission to
clarify that the Final Rule's ARC requirement would not undermine or
require any changes to existing aggregation programs that already
function well.\51\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\50\ Id. at 14 (citing TAPS NOPR Comments at 13-17).
\51\ Id. at 14-15.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
34. According to TAPS, load-serving entity based programs provide
significant value to all of their customers because load-serving
entities can integrate their demand response programs into their power
supply resource planning. This allows interruptions to be predictable
and avoids the need to carry planning reserve for interruptible load.
TAPS adds that customers can enjoy the protection of load-serving
entity power supply planning and aggregation and average cost rates
when they do not want to lower their consumption while wholesale prices
are high.
35. TAPS argues that the Commission's attempt to direct demand
response into the RTO's or ISO's wholesale energy and ancillary
services markets will cause load-serving entities to lose the planning
benefits that a load-serving-entity-administered demand response
program would normally provide. The load-serving entity would need to
include in its planning for firm power supply the full loads of its
retail customers who sell into wholesale markets or contract with ARCs,
as well as carry full planning reserves to meet that load. Thus, TAPS
asserts, the value to the load-serving entity and its other customers
of avoiding peak block generation investments and additional reserves
would be lost.\52\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\52\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
36. Similarly, Joint Petitioners note that many public power
systems and cooperatives have effectively acted as ARCs for their
retail customers. This benefits customers because these not-for-profit
entities pass on any savings from demand response measures to their
customers in the form of lower rates. Joint Petitioners conclude that
ARCs' activities would undercut the demand response regimes their
public power systems and cooperatives already have in place or are
developing by cherry-picking the demand response potential of specific
retail customers, and reducing the savings to the customers of the
public power system accruing from such programs.\53\ Also, they contend
that allowing ARCs to selectively choose load-serving entity demand
response resources would also deprive those load-serving entities of
important resources used to keep rates down for all consumers. Load-
serving entities could no longer control individual customers' loads
and engage in risk and portfolio management on behalf of their
customers.\54\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\53\ Joint Petitioners at 14-15.
\54\ Id. at 15.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
37. TAPS further argues that, by authorizing retail customers to
sell their non-consumption at high spot prices, the Final Rule changes
the financial calculation for retail customers considering demand
response. TAPS claims that this reduces load-serving entities' or
customers' incentives to make the capital investments necessary to
achieve significant, permanent reductions in electricity usage, in
favor of short-term, peak-hour reductions that garner premium payments
from ARCs and the wholesale market.\55\ TAPS argues that the load-
serving entity's loss of control over its retail customers' demand
response could impair the load-serving entity's ability to plan for its
load and harness that demand response to reduce the costs of serving
all of its customers.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\55\ TAPS at 17.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
38. Also, TAPS asserts that permitting direct demand response
participation in wholesale markets and aggregation by third-party ARCs
will significantly affect billing, metering, and settlement for the
municipal system at both the wholesale and retail levels. Specifically,
it contends that any system implemented by RTOs and ISOs to prevent
double-counting could require major modifications to both RTO and ISO
metering and settlement protocols and load-serving entities' metering
and billing protocols.\56\ For example, TAPS states that municipals
that allow individual retail customers and third-party ARCs to sell
demand response into wholesale markets may be subject to phantom energy
charges,\57\ based on
[[Page 37782]]
the amount of energy that those retail demand responders would
otherwise have consumed. Consequently, this could result in deviation
charges for load-serving entities for failure to accurately schedule
their load. TAPS argues that, if ARC-aggregated load causes an
unexpected drop in a load-serving entity's load, the load-serving
entity will be subject to uplift charges if its real-time load is below
its day-ahead load.\58\ Similarly, it adds that a decrease or an
increase in a load-serving entity's load, triggered by unexpected,
market-price driven demand response, could impose over- and under-
scheduling charges on a load-serving entity under the SPP's tariff.\59\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\56\ Id. at 18.
\57\ TAPS provides the following example to explain ``phantom
energy'':
[I]f a [transmission-dependent entity] with 100 MW of metered
load in a given hour has a retail customer that has sold 5 MW of
demand response energy into the RTO's energy imbalance market in
that same hour, then to avoid double-counting the demand response
that is already reflected in the [load-serving entity's] metered
load, the RTO would charge the [load-serving entity] for 105 MWh of
energy--i.e. as if the 5 MWh of demand response energy had been
purchased by the [load-serving entity], delivered to the retail
customer, and then re-sold. Id. at 19-20.
\58\ Id. at 22. TAPS notes that such a deviation charge may not
apply during an emergency, as provided elsewhere in Order No. 719.
\59\ Id. (citing Southwest Power Pool, FERC Electric Tariff,
Fifth Revised Volume No. 1, Attachment AE, sections 5.3 and 5.4).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
39. Arguing that demand response participation in wholesale
markets, either directly or by third-party ARCs, will affect the
scheduling and resource planning of the load-serving entities that
serve the retail customers providing demand response, TAPS concludes
that load-serving entities will need to develop a system for allocating
the cost of phantom energy. TAPS believes that load-serving entities
should assign those charges only to retail customers whose decision to
sell their demand response into the wholesale market caused the load-
serving entity to incur those costs. Accordingly, TAPS requests that
the Final Rule should be modified to direct RTOs and ISOs to provide
detailed information, in real time, to affected load-serving entities
on: (1) The identity of all individual retail customer load involved
(even if aggregated by an ARC); and (2) the amount of such demand
response for each billing interval.\60\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\60\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
40. TAPS believes that, in total, the costs of accommodating
wholesale demand response bids by selected retail customers outweigh
the benefits. It asserts that the implementation of the Final Rule to
accommodate wholesale demand response bids by retail customers will
require RTOs and ISOs and load-serving entities to expend resources for
uncertain benefits. For example, TAPS states that RTOs and ISOs will
incur significant costs to design brand-new systems to accommodate,
track, and verify demand response. Therefore, it asks that the
Commission require RTOs and ISOs to evaluate the efficacy of ARC-based
demand response programs, especially given the adverse impacts on load-
serving-entity-administered demand response programs, and to implement
them only if that evaluation demonstrates that the benefits outweigh
the costs.\61\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\61\ Id. at 22-23.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
b. Commission Determination
41. In the Final Rule, the Commission adopted the NOPR proposal to
require RTOs and ISOs to amend their market rules as necessary to
permit an ARC to bid demand response on behalf of retail customers
directly into the RTO's or ISO's organized markets, unless the laws or
regulations of the relevant electric retail regulatory authority do not
permit a retail customer to participate. The Commission reasoned that
such an action would reduce a barrier to demand response participation
in the organized markets subject to Commission jurisdiction.\62\ As
discussed below, we affirm this broad finding, but deny in part and
grant in part requests for rehearing on this issue.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\62\ Order No. 719, FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 31,281 at P 594; NOPR,
FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 32,628 at P 83.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
i. Commission Jurisdiction
42. Although the rehearing requests present the issue of Commission
jurisdiction from various points of view and with emphasis on various
groups of market participants or activities (and we will answer these
arguments in turn), they all include the same basic issue: whether the
Commission has jurisdiction to make rules requiring the RTOs and ISOs
to accept demand response bids.
43. Section 201(b) of the FPA confers jurisdiction on the
Commission over the transmission of electric energy in interstate
commerce, and sales of electric energy at wholesale in interstate
commerce.\63\ Sections 205 and 206 of the FPA confer upon the
Commission the responsibility to ensure that rates and charges for
transmission and wholesale power sales by public utilities, including
any rule, regulation, practice or contract affecting them, are just and
reasonable and not unduly discriminatory or preferential.\64\ While FPA
sections 201(f) and 201(b)(2) make clear that the Commission's
authorities under Part II of the FPA do not apply to governmental
entities and certain electric cooperatives, except as specifically
provided, the Commission's regulation of the organized markets operated
by RTOs and ISOs (which are public utilities) nevertheless affects
governmental and cooperative entities that participate in those
markets.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\63\ 16 U.S.C. 824(b).
\64\ Section 205(a) of the FPA charges the Commission with
ensuring that rates and charges for jurisdictional sales by public
utilities and ``all rules and regulations affecting or pertaining to
such rates or charges'' are just and reasonable. Id. 824d(a).
Section 206(a) gives the Commission authority over rate and charges
by public utilities for jurisdictional sales as well as ``any rule,
regulation, practice or contract affecting such rates and charges''
to make sure that they are just and reasonable and not unduly
discriminatory or preferential. Id. 824e(a).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
44. In exercising its FPA section 206 authority to regulate public
utility wholesale sales, the Commission concluded that well-functioning
competitive wholesale electric markets should reflect current supply
and demand conditions, and that wholesale markets work best when demand
can respond to the wholesale price. Thus, the Commission began this
proceeding with the goal of eliminating those barriers to demand
response participation in the organized markets, and to ensure
comparable treatment of all resources in these markets.\65\ The Final
Rule's ARC requirement is one element of the Commission's effort to
achieve this goal.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\65\ In Order No. 890, the Commission found that sales of
ancillary services by ``load services. * * * should be permitted
where appropriate on a comparable basis to service provided by
generation resources.'' Order No. 890, FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 31,241
(2007).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
45. Courts have recognized that the Commission has broad authority
under the FPA to identify practices that ``affect'' public utility
wholesale rates under the FPA.\66\ For instance, most recently, the DC
Circuit held that it was within the Commission's jurisdiction to review
ISO New England's annual calculation of the minimum amount of wholesale
electric capacity that must be available to assure reliable service in
the New England region.\67\ The court stated that ``even if all the
[Installed Capacity Requirement] did was help to find the right price,
it would still amount to a `practice * * * affecting rates' '' for
purposes of Commission authority.\68\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\66\ See, e.g., City of Cleveland v. FERC, 773 F.2d 1368, 1376
(D.C. Cir. 1985) (``[T]here is an infinitude of practices affecting
rates and service. * * * It is obviously left to the Commission,
within broad bounds of discretion, to give concrete application to
this amorphous directive.'').
\67\ Connecticut Dep't of Public Util. Control v. FERC, No. 07-
1375, slip op. at 14-15 (D.C. Cir. June 23, 2009).
\68\ Id. at 15. The court further stated that ``[w]here capacity
decisions about an interconnected bulk power system affect
[Commission]-jurisdictional transmission rates for that system * * *
they come within the Commission's authority,'' adding that ``there
is nothing special about capacity decisions that places them beyond
the Commission's jurisdiction''. Id. at 14-15.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
[[Page 37783]]
46. The Commission has found on several occasions that demand
response affects wholesale markets, rates, and practices and,
therefore, issued orders on various aspects of electric demand response
in organized markets. Some of these orders approved various types of
demand response programs, including programs to allow demand response
to be used as a capacity resource \69\ and as a resource during system
emergencies,\70\ to allow wholesale buyers and qualifying large retail
buyers to bid demand response directly into the day-ahead and real-time
energy markets and certain ancillary services markets, particularly as
a provider of operating reserves, as well as programs to accept bids
from ARCs.\71\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\69\ See, e.g., PJM Interconnection, LLC, 117 FERC ] 61,331
(2006); Devon Power L.L.C., 115 FERC ] 61,340, order on reh'g, 117
FERC ] 61,133 (2006).
\70\ See, e.g., New York Indep. Sys. Operator, Inc., 95 FERC ]
61,136 (2001); NSTAR Services Co. v. New England Power Pool, 95 FERC
] 61,250 (2001); New England Power Pool and ISO New England, Inc.,
100 FERC ] 61,287, order on reh'g, 101 FERC ] 61,344 (2002), order
on reh'g, 103 FERC ] 61,304, order on reh'g, 105 FERC ] 61,211
(2003); PJM Interconnection, LLC, 99 FERC ] 61,139 (2002).
\71\ See, e.g., New York Indep. Sys. Operator, Inc., 95 FERC ]
61,223 (2001); New England Power Pool and ISO New England, Inc., 100
FERC ] 61,287, order on reh'g, 101 FERC ] 61,344 (2002), order on
reh'g, 103 FERC ] 61,304, order on reh'g, 105 FERC ] 61,211 (2003);
PJM Interconnection, LLC, 99 FERC ] 61,227 (2002).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
47. Demand response affects public utility wholesale rates because
decreasing demand will tend to result in lower prices and less price
volatility.\72\ The Commission has noted that demand response has both
a direct and an indirect effect on wholesale prices. The direct effect
occurs when demand response is bid directly into the wholesale market:
lower demand means a lower wholesale price. Demand response at the
retail level affects the wholesale market indirectly because it reduces
a load-serving entity's need to purchase power from the wholesale
market.\73\ Demand response tends to flatten an area's load profile,
which in turn may reduce the need to construct and use more costly
resources during periods of high demand; the overall effect is to lower
the average cost of producing energy.\74\ Demand response can help
reduce generator market power: the more demand response is able to
reduce peak prices, the more downward pressure it places on generator
bidding strategies by increasing the risk to a supplier that it will
not be dispatched if it bids a price that is too high.\75\ Moreover,
demand response enhances system reliability.\76\ Thus, because demand
response directly affects wholesale rates, reducing barriers to demand
response in the organized wholesale markets helps the Commission to
fulfill its responsibility, under sections 205 and 206 of the FPA, for
ensuring that those rates are just and reasonable.\77\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\72\ ANOPR, FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 32,617 at P 37.
\73\ NOPR, FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 32,628 at P 29.
\74\ Id. P 30. Increasing the presence of demand response also
provides market participants with better information about where
they should and should not construct upgrades. ``In current market
contexts, constructing new generation facilities in response to a
higher [installed capacity requirement] may even feel like an
imperative. But petitioners have posited no source for that feeling
other than internalization of the true costs of the alternatives,
which is not only a requirement for efficient market outcomes, but,
again, something the Commission may concededly pursue.'' Connecticut
Dep't of Public Util. Control v. FERC, No. 07-1375, slip op. at 11
(D.C. Cir. June 23, 2009).
\75\ NOPR, FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 32,628 at P 31.
\76\ For example, ``[b]y reducing electricity demand at critical
times (e.g., when a generator or a transmission line unexpectedly
fails), demand response that is dispatched by the system operator on
short notice can help return electric syst