Public Hearings Concerning the Evolving Intellectual Property Marketplace, 70645-70648 [E8-27673]
Download as PDF
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 226 / Friday, November 21, 2008 / Notices
Calculation of (Ri + RSi), Total Amount
of Renewable Fuel Blended Into
Gasoline That Is Projected To Be
Consumed in the 48 Contiguous States
Plus Opt-In States/Territories, in Year i,
in Gallons
The projected gasoline consumption
in the October 2008 STEO includes
renewable fuel that is blended into
gasoline. This volume of renewable fuel
must be subtracted from the total
volume of gasoline in order to calculate
the total consumption of non-renewable
gasoline. In Table 8 of the October 2008
STEO, EIA estimates that 0.929
quadrillion Btu of ethanol will be used
as transportation fuel in all of the
United States in 2009. Dividing this
energy usage by the high heating value
of ethanol (3.539 million Btu/barrel),
and multiplying by 42 gallons/barrel
produces a total projected ethanol usage
of 11.03 billion gallons nationwide in
2009.
Since Hawaii has opted in, but Alaska
has not opted in, to the RFS program for
2009, Alaska’s renewable fuels
consumption must be subtracted from
the nationwide renewable fuels
consumption to calculate renewable
consumption in the 48 contiguous states
plus Hawaii. In Chapter 2 of the
Regulatory Impact Analysis for the RFS1
program rulemaking, EPA estimated that
ethanol consumption in Alaska would
be negligible prior to 2012.3 Thus,
calculated projected renewable fuels
consumption in the 48 contiguous states
plus Hawaii is 11.03 billion gallons in
2009, slightly lower than the RFS for
2009.
RFStdi = 100 ×
Therefore, the RFS for 2009 is
10.21%. This is the standard referenced
in 40 CFR 80.1105(b) through (d) and
which obligated parties apply to
determine their renewable volume
obligation under 40 CFR 80.1107.
Dated: November 14, 2008.
Robert J. Meyers,
Principal Deputy Assistant Administrator,
Office of Air and Radiation.
[FR Doc. E8–27613 Filed 11–20–08; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6560–50–P
FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION
Public Hearings Concerning the
Evolving Intellectual Property
Marketplace
dwashington3 on PRODPC61 with NOTICES
AGENCY:
Federal Trade Commission.
2 Energy Information Administration, Petroleum
Marketing Annual 2007, Explanatory Notes,
Relationship of Refiner and Prime Supplier Sales
Volumes’’ (p. 393).
3 Table 2.2–21 ‘‘2012 Forecasted Ethanol
Consumption by State,’’ Regulatory Impact
VerDate Aug<31>2005
14:24 Nov 20, 2008
Jkt 217001
Calculation of GEi, Amount of Gasoline
Projected To Be Produced by Exempt
Small Refineries and Small Refiners in
Year i, in Gallons 4
In the final rulemaking establishing
the RFS1 program regulations, we stated
that we would estimate the combined
small refinery and small refiner gasoline
volume using a constant percentage of
national consumption. Using
information from gasoline batch reports
submitted to EPA, EIA data and input
from the California Air Resources Board
regarding California small refiners, we
estimated this percentage to be 13.5%.5
Multiplying the projected nationwide
consumption of gasoline in 2009 (138.74
billion gallons) by 13.5% results in a
total projected production of 18.73
billion gallons of gasoline from small
refiners and small refineries in 2009.
Calculation of RFStdi, Renewable Fuel
Standard in Year i, in Percent
Substituting all of the terms
calculated above into the equation for
RFStdi results in the following RFS for
2009,
11.1
= 10.21%
138.47 − 11.03 − 18.73
Notice of Public Hearings
SUMMARY: The Federal Trade
Commission will hold a series of public
hearings beginning on December 5,
2008, in Washington, D.C., to explore
the evolving market for intellectual
property (IP). The hearings will examine
changes in intellectual property law,
patent-related business models, and
new learning regarding the operation of
the IP marketplace since the FTC issued
its October 2003 report, To Promote
Innovation: The Proper Balance of
Competition and Patent Law and Policy
(the FTC IP Report).1 Changes and
proposed changes in the law, together
with evolving business models for
buying, selling and licensing IP, could
significantly influence a patent’s
economic value and the operation of the
IP marketplace. The hearings will
consider the impact of these changes on
innovation, competition and consumer
welfare.
The Commission seeks the views of
the legal, academic, and business
communities on the issues to be
explored at the hearings. This notice
poses a series of questions relevant to
those issues on which the Commission
seeks comment. Each hearing will be
transcribed. The transcript and any
written comments received will be
placed on the public record.
DATES: The first hearing will be held
December 5, 2008, in the Conference
Center of the FTC office building at 601
New Jersey Avenue, N.W., Washington,
D.C. All interested parties are welcome
to attend. An agenda for that hearing
will be posted on the FTC’s website,
www.ftc.gov. The Commission may hold
Analysis: Renewable Fuel Standard Program, April
2007.
4 Through 2010 only, unless the exemption is
extended under 211(o)(9)(A)(ii) or (B) of the Act.
5 ‘‘Calculation of the Small Refiner/Small
Refinery Fraction for the Renewable Fuel Program,’’
memo to the docket from Christine Brunner, ASD,
OTAQ, EPA, September 2006.
1 Federal Trade Commission, To Promote
Innovation: The Proper Balance of Competition
and Patent Law and Policy (October 2003),
available at (https://www.ftc.gov/os/2003/10/
innovationrpt.pdf) (‘‘IP Report’’).
ACTION:
PO 00000
Frm 00034
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
E:\FR\FM\21NON1.SGM
21NON1
EN21NO08.001
consumption of 138.74 billion gallons.
Alaska’s projected gasoline
consumption was calculated by
multiplying the projected nationwide
gasoline consumption in 2009 by the
ratio of Alaska’s gasoline consumption
in 2007 to the total U.S. consumption in
2007, based on Table 45, ‘‘Prime
Supplier Sales Volumes of Motor
Gasoline by Grade Formulation, PAD
District, and State’’ gasoline data from
EIA’s Petroleum Marketing Annual 2007
(the final rulemaking used data from
Petroleum Marketing Annual 2005).
According to EIA, Prime Supplier data
reflects where gasoline is used, rather
than where it is produced.2 Alaska’s
projected gasoline consumption in 2009
is 0.27 billion gallons. Subtracting this
consumption from the projected
nationwide consumption of 138.74
billion gallons in 2009 produces a total
consumption of 138.47 billion gallons of
gasoline in 2009 in the 48 contiguous
states plus Hawaii.
70645
70646
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 226 / Friday, November 21, 2008 / Notices
dwashington3 on PRODPC61 with NOTICES
subsequent hearings in Washington,
D.C. and other locations. Prior to each
hearing, the Commission will publish
an agenda on its website.
ADDRESSES: Any interested person may
submit written comments responsive to
any of the topics identified in this
Federal Register notice or in any
subsequent announcement related to
hearings on the Evolving IP
Marketplace. Respondents are
encouraged to provide comments as
soon as possible, but no later than
February 5, 2009. The FTC will only
accept comments submitted by weblink
or in hard copy format. Information
about how to submit comments will be
posted on the website for the hearings,
accessible at (https://www.ftc.gov/ftc/
workshops.shtm).
The FTC Act and other laws the
Commission administers permit the
collection of public comments to
consider and use in this proceeding as
appropriate. The Commission will
consider all timely and responsive
public comments that it receives,
whether filed in paper or electronic
form. Comments received will be
available to the public on the FTC
website, to the extent practicable, at
https://www.ftc.gov. As a matter of
discretion, the FTC makes every effort to
remove home contact information for
individuals from the public comments it
receives before placing those comments
on the FTC website. More information,
including routine uses permitted by the
Privacy Act, may be found in the FTC’s
privacy policy, at (https://www.ftc.gov/
ftc/privacy.shtm.)
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
Erika Meyers, Office of Policy and
Coordination, Bureau of Competition,
601 New Jersey Avenue, N.W.,
Washington, D.C. 20580; telephone 202326-2076; e-mail,
IPMarketPlace@ftc.gov.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION:
The October 2003 FTC IP Report
The FTC is an antitrust enforcement
agency, but it also has a mandate to
study issues related to competition
policy. In 2002, the agency undertook a
study of the patent system under both
of these roles in response to the
increasing significance of patents in the
knowledge-based economy and the role
of dynamic, innovation-based
considerations in antitrust analysis. In
support of the study, the FTC and the
Department of Justice held over 24 days
of hearings that involved more than 300
panelists, including representatives
from large and small business firms; the
independent inventor community;
patent and antitrust organizations; and
VerDate Aug<31>2005
14:24 Nov 20, 2008
Jkt 217001
the academic community in economics
and antitrust and patent law. In
addition, the FTC received about 100
written submissions. Many of the
business representatives were from
technology-intensive industries such as
pharmaceuticals, biotechnology,
computer hardware and software, and
the Internet. The Report FTC’s October
2003 Report on the patent system, To
Promote Innovation: The Proper
Balance of Competition and Patent Law
and Policy,2 summarizes testimony from
the hearings and explains the
Commission’s recommendations for
improving the patent system.
The IP Report found that both
competition and patents influence
innovation, which drives economic
growth and increases standards of
living. Patents play an important role in
promoting innovation by providing an
incentive to develop and commercialize
inventions. Without patent protection,
innovators that produce intellectual
property may not be able to appropriate
the full benefits of their innovation
when competitors are able to ‘‘free ride’’
on the innovator’s efforts. Patents may
also encourage firms to compete in the
race to invent new products and
processes. Patent rights make it easier
for inventors to attract funding and
enter the licensing and joint-venture
arrangements needed to commercialize
an invention. Moreover, the public
disclosure of scientific and technical
information made through a patent can
stimulate further scientific progress.
The IP Report explained that
competition also plays a critical role in
stimulating innovation. Competition
drives firms to identify consumers’
unmet needs and develop new products
and services to satisfy them. In some
industries, firms race to innovate in
hopes of exploiting first-mover
advantages. The IP Report raises
concerns that patents of questionable
quality-those of questionable validity or
having overly broad claims-can hinder
competition and innovation in several
ways, to the detriment of consumers.
For instance, patents of questionable
quality can deter follow-on innovation
2 I.P. Report, supra n.1. In 2007, the Federal
Trade Commission and the Antitrust Division of the
Department of Justice released a joint report based
on these hearings examining the ways in which
antitrust analysis should take into account the
patent system’s incentives to innovate. The report
recognizes that the way antitrust law functions at
the patent interface can significantly affect IPdriven innovation. U.S. Dep’t of Justice and the
Federal Trade Commission, Antitrust Enforcement
and Intellectual Property Rights: Promoting
Innovation and Competition (April 2007) available
at (https://www.ftc.gov/reports/innovation/
P040101Promoting
Innovationand
Competitionrpt0704.pdf)
PO 00000
Frm 00035
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
by discouraging firms from conducting
research and development in areas that
the patent improperly covers, and raise
costs when challenged in litigation or
unnecessarily licensed. The IP Report
made ten recommendations for
legislative, judicial and administrative
changes to the patent system to address
these concerns, several of which have
come to pass or received support in
Congress. Those recommendations
include establishing a more flexible
obviousness standard under 35 U.S.C.
§ 103, raising the requirements for
proving willful infringement, and
instituting a patent post-grant review
procedure in the Patent and Trademark
Office.
Recent Changes to the Patent System
The patent system has experienced
significant change since the FTC
released its first IP Report in October
2003, and more changes are under
consideration. The courts and patentees
are exploring the full implications of
Supreme Court and Federal Circuit
decisions on injunctive relief,
patentability and licensing issues.
Congress has considered sweeping
legislative patent reform, and new
debates on the appropriate methods for
calculating infringement damages have
engaged the patent community. New
business models for buying, selling and
licensing patents have emerged and
evolved since 2003. In addition, there is
new learning regarding the operation of
the patent system and its contribution to
innovation and competition.
Three of these recent developments
have brought the issues of patent
remedies and their impact on
innovation and consumers to the
forefront. In 2006, the Supreme Court
ruled in eBay v. MercExchange3 that
district courts may no longer
automatically grant a permanent
injunction barring future infringement
following a finding of infringement, but
must consider traditional principles of
equity. In 2007, in In re. Seagate
Technologies, Inc.,4 the Court of
Appeals for the Federal Circuit
abandoned its ‘‘duty of due care’’
standard, and held that proof of willful
infringement requires ‘‘at least a
showing of objective recklessness,’’ thus
making it more difficult for a patentee
to obtain treble damages. While the
patent system grapples with the
application of those decisions, debate
continues in the patent community over
the appropriate methods for calculating
3
4
547 U.S. 388 (2006).
497 F.3d 1360, 1371 (Fed. Cir. 2007).
E:\FR\FM\21NON1.SGM
21NON1
dwashington3 on PRODPC61 with NOTICES
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 226 / Friday, November 21, 2008 / Notices
reasonable royalty damages and whether
legislative changes are needed.
Remedies available in patent
litigation—a permanent injunction
barring future infringement,
compensatory damages for past
infringement, and trebled damages for
willful infringement—play an important
role in determining the value of all
patents. The parties’ assessment of the
remedy a court might award heavily
influences the settlements that resolve
the vast majority of patent infringement
actions, and even licensing negotiations
that take place without the initiation of
a court action. Thus, these changes and
proposed changes could have farreaching effects on the value of patents
and the operation of the market for
intellectual property.
Three other recent Supreme Court
decisions affect the value of patents and
the operation of the IP marketplace
through rulings on what patents are
valid, when licensees may challenge
validity, and who may owe royalties. In
KSR International v. Teleflex, Inc.,5 the
Supreme Court propounded a flexible
approach to obviousness doctrine. In
doing so, the Court discussed the
detrimental effects of obvious patents,
which withdraw from the public what is
already known and diminish the
resources available to support
innovation. In Medimmune, Inc. v.
Genentech, Inc.,6 the Court allowed a
patent licensee to challenge a patent’s
validity through a declaratory judgment
action because the harm of paying
royalties on an invalid patent generates
a ‘‘substantial controversy between
parties having adverse legal interests.’’7
In Quanta Computer Inc. v. LG
Electronics,8 the Court affirmed the
exhaustion doctrine even where the
initial patent license purported to limit
the rights transferred to subsequent
purchasers of a covered product.
Some of the most significant recent
changes in markets for intellectual
property have occurred not through the
courts, but through the emergence of
new business models involving the
buying, selling and licensing of patents.
Companies have always used
intellectual property as a strategic asset:
sometimes offensively to maintain
exclusivity over a technology, to capture
royalties from competing products, or to
support technology transfer, and
sometimes defensively, to stave off
potential infringement litigation. New
business models have emerged in recent
years, however. Some business models
127 S. Ct. 1727 (2007).
549 U.S. 118 (2007).
7 Id. at 771.
8 128 S.Ct. 2109 (2008).
5
6
VerDate Aug<31>2005
14:24 Nov 20, 2008
Jkt 217001
seek to monetize patents based on
strategic acquisition and assertion.
Others establish a cooperative venture
that buys and licenses patents to its
members for defensive purposes. Still
others seek to create sector-specific
funds, similar to mutual funds, that
allow investors to earn revenue from
royalty streams. There are likely other
developing business models that use
intellectual property as their primary
asset.
Hearings on the Evolving IP
Marketplace.
The extent and cumulative impact of
these changes and proposed changes on
the patent system are poorly
understood. They could potentially
significantly influence a patent’s
economic value and a patentee’s
compensation. If patentees were
systematically under-compensated due
to legal doctrines that drive down the
value received through remedies and
licensing, patents would be devalued.
This would undermine the patent
system’s incentives to innovate, to the
detriment of consumers who benefit
tremendously from innovation. On the
other hand, if the relevant legal rules
operate to systematically
overcompensate patentees, supracompetitive prices for technology would
unduly dampen future innovation, and
prices for products incorporating
patented inventions would increase
unjustifiably. Both under- and
overcompensation of patentees present
the potential for consumer and
competitive harm.
The Commission plans to hold a
series of hearings that will examine the
recent and proposed changes in the IP
marketplace and consider the effects of
those changes on the alignment of
patent and competition policy. The first
hearing will occur on December 5, 2008
in Washington, D.C.
The December 5th hearing will
include three panels addressing a range
of topics related to the valuation of
patents and the operation of the market
for intellectual property. A primary goal
of this first hearing is to identify those
issues that require more in-depth study
in subsequent hearings. In the first
panel, participants will discuss the
operation and impact of emerging
business models, aspects of the patent
system that support those models, and
industry responses. The second panel
will explore remedies law and the need
for economic analysis in this area. In the
third panel, participants will examine
legal doctrines that affect the value and
licensing of patents, such as the recent
Supreme Court cases on obviousness,
declaratory judgment and exhaustion,
PO 00000
Frm 00036
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
70647
and doctrines that make the scope and
enforcement of patents unpredictable.
The panel will consider whether the
notice function of patents operates to
support an efficient marketplace.
The Commission invites public
comments discussing the current
marketplace for intellectual property, in
particular its impact on innovation
incentives and competition concerns
and the role of economic analysis in this
assessment. The Commission will
accept comments, as described above,
until February 5, 2009. Comments
addressing any of the following
questions would be particularly helpful.
1. How has the IP marketplace
changed in the past five to ten years?
What changes are expected in the
future? What aspects of the patent
system drive those changes? What is the
impact of those changes on innovation?
2. What are the new business models
involving intellectual property? What
has motivated the development of these
business models? What is their impact
on innovation?
3. What economic evidence is
relevant when analyzing whether to
grant a permanent injunction following
a finding of infringement? What proof
have courts required? How should the
analysis take into account the incentives
to innovate provided by the patent
system and the benefits of competition?
What is the appropriate remedy when
the court has denied a permanent
injunction after a finding of
infringement?
4. Do the legal rules governing patent
damages result in awards that
appropriately compensate patentees?
Are there circumstances in which they
result in overcompensation or
undercompensation of patentees? What
evidence is there of the extent of these
problems? What information would be
helpful to better assess whether damage
awards appropriately compensate
patentees? Are courts and juries able to
make damages determinations with
sufficient accuracy? To the extent that
there are problems resulting from the
determination of damages for patent
infringement, how should they be
addressed?
5. How have changes in willfulness
doctrine changed the behavior of
patentees and potential infringers? Do
recent changes in the law adequately
address the concerns with willfulness
doctrine identified in the October 2003
FTC IP Report?
6. How will changes in patent law
rendered by Supreme Court and Federal
Circuit decisions of the past five years
affect the value of patents? How will
these changes affect the operation of the
E:\FR\FM\21NON1.SGM
21NON1
70648
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 226 / Friday, November 21, 2008 / Notices
IP marketplace? How will they affect
innovation and competition?
7. How does uncertainty regarding the
validity and scope of patents affect the
operation of the IP marketplace? Does
the current system adequately fulfill the
notice function of patents? How does
uncertainty influence the operation of
the IP marketplace? What are the
sources of uncertainty that affect the
value of patents and the operation of the
IP marketplace? What could be done to
address them?
8. How transparent is the current IP
marketplace? Can it be made more
transparent? Is that desirable?
9. During the past five years, what
new learning has furthered the
understanding of the patent system and
the IP marketplace?
By direction of the Commission.
Donald S. Clark,
Secretary.
[FR Doc. E8–27673 Filed 11–20–08: 8:45 am]
[BILLING CODE 6750–01–S]
DEPARTMENT OF HEALTH AND
HUMAN SERVICES
Agency for Healthcare Research and
Quality
Agency Information Collection
Activities: Proposed Collection;
Comment Request
Agency for Healthcare Research
and Quality, HHS.
ACTION: Notice.
dwashington3 on PRODPC61 with NOTICES
AGENCY:
SUMMARY: This notice announces the
intention of the Agency for Healthcare
Research and Quality (AHRQ) to request
that the Office of Management and
Budget (OMB) approve the proposed
information collection project:
‘‘Reducing Waste and Inefficiency
through Process Redesign: Lean/Toyota
Production System (TPS)
Implementation.’’ In accordance with
the Paperwork Reduction Act of 1995,
44 U.S.C. 3506(c)(2)(A), AHRQ invites
the public to comment on this proposed
information collection.
DATES: Comments on this notice must be
received by (insert date 60 days after
date of publication).
ADDRESSES: Written comments should
be submitted to: Doris Lefkowitz,
Reports Clearance Officer, AHRQ, by
email at doris.lefkowitz@ahrq.hhs.gov.
Copies of the proposed collection
plans, data collection instruments, and
specific details on the estimated burden
can be obtained from the AHRQ Reports
Clearance Officer.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
Doris Lefkowitz, AHRQ Reports
VerDate Aug<31>2005
14:24 Nov 20, 2008
Jkt 217001
Clearance Officer, (301) 427–1477, or by
email at doris.lefkowitz@ahrq.hhs.gov..
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION:
Proposed Project
‘‘Reducing Waste and Inefficiency
through Process Redesign: Lean/Toyota
Production System (TPS)
Implementation’’ AHRQ, through its
contractor, American Institutes for
Research (AIR), proposes to investigate
the contribution of Lean/TPS to
reducing waste in health care delivery
systems. Lean is a process-redesign
methodology adopted from Toyota
Production Systems. The goal of Lean/
TPS is to empower front-line staff to
apply continuous quality improvement
methods to reduce waste and enhance
value in workflows and operations
(Spear, S. Fixing healthcare from the
inside, today. Harvard Business Rev.,
2005 83(9), 78–91). AHRQ is interested
in assessing and disseminating
promising techniques and
methodologies for redesigning health
care processes to reduce waste and
enhance efficiency. Using a purposive
sample of health care organizations and
projects, AHRQ will describe and assess
the ways in which Lean/TPS has been
implemented and the related challenges
and solutions experienced. The sample
will vary in community and market
characteristics, type of service (e.g.,
inpatient/outpatient), and delivery
system characteristics (e.g., relationship
between physicians and hospitals,
ownership). AHRQ plans to disseminate
the lessons learned from this project on
the implementation of Lean/TPS to
health care delivery systems. This
project is being conducted pursuant to
AHRQ’s statutory authority to conduct
and support research on health care and
on systems for the delivery of such care,
including activities with respect to: The
quality, effectiveness, efficiency,
appropriateness and value of health care
services; quality measurement and
improvement; and health care costs,
productivity, organization, and market
forces. 42 U.S.C. 299a(a)(1), (2), and (6).
Method of Collection
At least four research locations (i.e.,
hospitals or other health settings) will
be selected to create eight case study
reports. Four of the studies will employ
a retrospective analytics perspective,
while four will employ a prospective
analytics perspective. At each location,
implementation of Lean/TPS in two
departments will be studied: One
department with an essentially linear
process (clinical laboratory, radiology,
or ED) and one department with an
essentially non-linear process
(cardiology, GI, or med/surg unit). A
PO 00000
Frm 00037
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
linear department is one in which the
process is essentially uniform and
predictable for most or all services
delivered. A non-linear department is
one in which the process is much less
uniform and predictable. If there is more
than one Lean/TPS project in the
selected department, we will
purposively select a project that appears
to have the most information for others
about the processes and outcomes of
Lean/TPS implementation.
Qualitative data will be collected
directly from the four locations selected
for this study. The collection will be
accomplished using interviews
telephone and in-person), collection of
documentation, and digital diaries for
the four prospective studies. The
‘‘digital diary’’ is a data collection
method using a diary entry guide and a
digital recorder to describe key aspects
of the implementation process. The total
number of in-person interviews to be
conducted across the four locations is
100; the total number of telephone
interviews is 36. The in-person
interviews will be conducted through a
multi-day visit to each site. The number
of digital diary submissions will depend
on the number and duration of the
Lean/TPS project within in each
department.
Estimated Annual Respondent Burden
Exhibit I shows the estimated
annualized burden hours. A total of 25
in-person interviews will be conducted
with the administrative and clinical
personnel from each of the four
participating health care facilities. The
estimated time per response is 1.0 hour
for a total of 100 burden hours.
Additionally, a total of 9 telephone
interviews will be conducted with each
facility. The estimated time per
response is 30 minutes, for a total of 18
burden hours. The digital diaries will be
completed once a month for eight
months by two personnel from each
facility, and will require about 30
minutes each per month for a total of 32
hours. Finally, administrative staff from
each site will be asked to provide
training materials, reports on Lean/TPS
implementation, and/or any other
documentation or existing data from
previous or current Lean/TPS projects
implemented. We anticipate this task
will simply consist of forwarding emails
and or photocopying and sending
documents to the project team one time
throughout the course of the project and
will take about four hours per facility or
16 hours total. The total estimated
burden is 166 hours. Exhibit 2 shows
the estimated annualized cost burden
for the respondents’ time to provide the
requested data. The hourly rate of
E:\FR\FM\21NON1.SGM
21NON1
Agencies
[Federal Register Volume 73, Number 226 (Friday, November 21, 2008)]
[Notices]
[Pages 70645-70648]
From the Federal Register Online via the Government Printing Office [www.gpo.gov]
[FR Doc No: E8-27673]
=======================================================================
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION
Public Hearings Concerning the Evolving Intellectual Property
Marketplace
AGENCY: Federal Trade Commission.
ACTION: Notice of Public Hearings
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
SUMMARY: The Federal Trade Commission will hold a series of public
hearings beginning on December 5, 2008, in Washington, D.C., to explore
the evolving market for intellectual property (IP). The hearings will
examine changes in intellectual property law, patent-related business
models, and new learning regarding the operation of the IP marketplace
since the FTC issued its October 2003 report, To Promote Innovation:
The Proper Balance of Competition and Patent Law and Policy (the FTC IP
Report).\1\ Changes and proposed changes in the law, together with
evolving business models for buying, selling and licensing IP, could
significantly influence a patent's economic value and the operation of
the IP marketplace. The hearings will consider the impact of these
changes on innovation, competition and consumer welfare.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1\ Federal Trade Commission, To Promote Innovation: The Proper
Balance of Competition and Patent Law and Policy (October 2003),
available at (https://www.ftc.gov/os/2003/10/innovationrpt.pdf) (``IP
Report'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The Commission seeks the views of the legal, academic, and business
communities on the issues to be explored at the hearings. This notice
poses a series of questions relevant to those issues on which the
Commission seeks comment. Each hearing will be transcribed. The
transcript and any written comments received will be placed on the
public record.
DATES: The first hearing will be held December 5, 2008, in the
Conference Center of the FTC office building at 601 New Jersey Avenue,
N.W., Washington, D.C. All interested parties are welcome to attend. An
agenda for that hearing will be posted on the FTC's website,
www.ftc.gov. The Commission may hold
[[Page 70646]]
subsequent hearings in Washington, D.C. and other locations. Prior to
each hearing, the Commission will publish an agenda on its website.
ADDRESSES: Any interested person may submit written comments responsive
to any of the topics identified in this Federal Register notice or in
any subsequent announcement related to hearings on the Evolving IP
Marketplace. Respondents are encouraged to provide comments as soon as
possible, but no later than February 5, 2009. The FTC will only accept
comments submitted by weblink or in hard copy format. Information about
how to submit comments will be posted on the website for the hearings,
accessible at (https://www.ftc.gov/ftc/workshops.shtm).
The FTC Act and other laws the Commission administers permit the
collection of public comments to consider and use in this proceeding as
appropriate. The Commission will consider all timely and responsive
public comments that it receives, whether filed in paper or electronic
form. Comments received will be available to the public on the FTC
website, to the extent practicable, at https://www.ftc.gov. As a matter
of discretion, the FTC makes every effort to remove home contact
information for individuals from the public comments it receives before
placing those comments on the FTC website. More information, including
routine uses permitted by the Privacy Act, may be found in the FTC's
privacy policy, at (https://www.ftc.gov/ftc/privacy.shtm.)
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: Erika Meyers, Office of Policy and
Coordination, Bureau of Competition, 601 New Jersey Avenue, N.W.,
Washington, D.C. 20580; telephone 202-326-2076; e-mail,
IPMarketPlace@ftc.gov.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION:
The October 2003 FTC IP Report
The FTC is an antitrust enforcement agency, but it also has a
mandate to study issues related to competition policy. In 2002, the
agency undertook a study of the patent system under both of these roles
in response to the increasing significance of patents in the knowledge-
based economy and the role of dynamic, innovation-based considerations
in antitrust analysis. In support of the study, the FTC and the
Department of Justice held over 24 days of hearings that involved more
than 300 panelists, including representatives from large and small
business firms; the independent inventor community; patent and
antitrust organizations; and the academic community in economics and
antitrust and patent law. In addition, the FTC received about 100
written submissions. Many of the business representatives were from
technology-intensive industries such as pharmaceuticals, biotechnology,
computer hardware and software, and the Internet. The Report FTC's
October 2003 Report on the patent system, To Promote Innovation: The
Proper Balance of Competition and Patent Law and Policy,\2\ summarizes
testimony from the hearings and explains the Commission's
recommendations for improving the patent system.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\2\ I.P. Report, supra n.1. In 2007, the Federal Trade
Commission and the Antitrust Division of the Department of Justice
released a joint report based on these hearings examining the ways
in which antitrust analysis should take into account the patent
system's incentives to innovate. The report recognizes that the way
antitrust law functions at the patent interface can significantly
affect IP-driven innovation. U.S. Dep't of Justice and the Federal
Trade Commission, Antitrust Enforcement and Intellectual Property
Rights: Promoting Innovation and Competition (April 2007) available
at (https://www.ftc.gov/reports/innovation/P040101Promoting
Innovationand Competitionrpt0704.pdf)
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The IP Report found that both competition and patents influence
innovation, which drives economic growth and increases standards of
living. Patents play an important role in promoting innovation by
providing an incentive to develop and commercialize inventions. Without
patent protection, innovators that produce intellectual property may
not be able to appropriate the full benefits of their innovation when
competitors are able to ``free ride'' on the innovator's efforts.
Patents may also encourage firms to compete in the race to invent new
products and processes. Patent rights make it easier for inventors to
attract funding and enter the licensing and joint-venture arrangements
needed to commercialize an invention. Moreover, the public disclosure
of scientific and technical information made through a patent can
stimulate further scientific progress.
The IP Report explained that competition also plays a critical role
in stimulating innovation. Competition drives firms to identify
consumers' unmet needs and develop new products and services to satisfy
them. In some industries, firms race to innovate in hopes of exploiting
first-mover advantages. The IP Report raises concerns that patents of
questionable quality-those of questionable validity or having overly
broad claims-can hinder competition and innovation in several ways, to
the detriment of consumers. For instance, patents of questionable
quality can deter follow-on innovation by discouraging firms from
conducting research and development in areas that the patent improperly
covers, and raise costs when challenged in litigation or unnecessarily
licensed. The IP Report made ten recommendations for legislative,
judicial and administrative changes to the patent system to address
these concerns, several of which have come to pass or received support
in Congress. Those recommendations include establishing a more flexible
obviousness standard under 35 U.S.C. Sec. 103, raising the
requirements for proving willful infringement, and instituting a patent
post-grant review procedure in the Patent and Trademark Office.
Recent Changes to the Patent System
The patent system has experienced significant change since the FTC
released its first IP Report in October 2003, and more changes are
under consideration. The courts and patentees are exploring the full
implications of Supreme Court and Federal Circuit decisions on
injunctive relief, patentability and licensing issues. Congress has
considered sweeping legislative patent reform, and new debates on the
appropriate methods for calculating infringement damages have engaged
the patent community. New business models for buying, selling and
licensing patents have emerged and evolved since 2003. In addition,
there is new learning regarding the operation of the patent system and
its contribution to innovation and competition.
Three of these recent developments have brought the issues of
patent remedies and their impact on innovation and consumers to the
forefront. In 2006, the Supreme Court ruled in eBay v. MercExchange\3\
that district courts may no longer automatically grant a permanent
injunction barring future infringement following a finding of
infringement, but must consider traditional principles of equity. In
2007, in In re. Seagate Technologies, Inc.,\4\ the Court of Appeals for
the Federal Circuit abandoned its ``duty of due care'' standard, and
held that proof of willful infringement requires ``at least a showing
of objective recklessness,'' thus making it more difficult for a
patentee to obtain treble damages. While the patent system grapples
with the application of those decisions, debate continues in the patent
community over the appropriate methods for calculating
[[Page 70647]]
reasonable royalty damages and whether legislative changes are needed.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\3\ 547 U.S. 388 (2006).
\4\ 497 F.3d 1360, 1371 (Fed. Cir. 2007).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Remedies available in patent litigation--a permanent injunction
barring future infringement, compensatory damages for past
infringement, and trebled damages for willful infringement--play an
important role in determining the value of all patents. The parties'
assessment of the remedy a court might award heavily influences the
settlements that resolve the vast majority of patent infringement
actions, and even licensing negotiations that take place without the
initiation of a court action. Thus, these changes and proposed changes
could have far-reaching effects on the value of patents and the
operation of the market for intellectual property.
Three other recent Supreme Court decisions affect the value of
patents and the operation of the IP marketplace through rulings on what
patents are valid, when licensees may challenge validity, and who may
owe royalties. In KSR International v. Teleflex, Inc.,\5\ the Supreme
Court propounded a flexible approach to obviousness doctrine. In doing
so, the Court discussed the detrimental effects of obvious patents,
which withdraw from the public what is already known and diminish the
resources available to support innovation. In Medimmune, Inc. v.
Genentech, Inc.,\6\ the Court allowed a patent licensee to challenge a
patent's validity through a declaratory judgment action because the
harm of paying royalties on an invalid patent generates a ``substantial
controversy between parties having adverse legal interests.''\7\ In
Quanta Computer Inc. v. LG Electronics,\8\ the Court affirmed the
exhaustion doctrine even where the initial patent license purported to
limit the rights transferred to subsequent purchasers of a covered
product.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\5\ 127 S. Ct. 1727 (2007).
\6\ 549 U.S. 118 (2007).
\7\ Id. at 771.
\8\ 128 S.Ct. 2109 (2008).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Some of the most significant recent changes in markets for
intellectual property have occurred not through the courts, but through
the emergence of new business models involving the buying, selling and
licensing of patents. Companies have always used intellectual property
as a strategic asset: sometimes offensively to maintain exclusivity
over a technology, to capture royalties from competing products, or to
support technology transfer, and sometimes defensively, to stave off
potential infringement litigation. New business models have emerged in
recent years, however. Some business models seek to monetize patents
based on strategic acquisition and assertion. Others establish a
cooperative venture that buys and licenses patents to its members for
defensive purposes. Still others seek to create sector-specific funds,
similar to mutual funds, that allow investors to earn revenue from
royalty streams. There are likely other developing business models that
use intellectual property as their primary asset.
Hearings on the Evolving IP Marketplace.
The extent and cumulative impact of these changes and proposed
changes on the patent system are poorly understood. They could
potentially significantly influence a patent's economic value and a
patentee's compensation. If patentees were systematically under-
compensated due to legal doctrines that drive down the value received
through remedies and licensing, patents would be devalued. This would
undermine the patent system's incentives to innovate, to the detriment
of consumers who benefit tremendously from innovation. On the other
hand, if the relevant legal rules operate to systematically
overcompensate patentees, supra-competitive prices for technology would
unduly dampen future innovation, and prices for products incorporating
patented inventions would increase unjustifiably. Both under- and
overcompensation of patentees present the potential for consumer and
competitive harm.
The Commission plans to hold a series of hearings that will examine
the recent and proposed changes in the IP marketplace and consider the
effects of those changes on the alignment of patent and competition
policy. The first hearing will occur on December 5, 2008 in Washington,
D.C.
The December 5\th\ hearing will include three panels addressing a
range of topics related to the valuation of patents and the operation
of the market for intellectual property. A primary goal of this first
hearing is to identify those issues that require more in-depth study in
subsequent hearings. In the first panel, participants will discuss the
operation and impact of emerging business models, aspects of the patent
system that support those models, and industry responses. The second
panel will explore remedies law and the need for economic analysis in
this area. In the third panel, participants will examine legal
doctrines that affect the value and licensing of patents, such as the
recent Supreme Court cases on obviousness, declaratory judgment and
exhaustion, and doctrines that make the scope and enforcement of
patents unpredictable. The panel will consider whether the notice
function of patents operates to support an efficient marketplace.
The Commission invites public comments discussing the current
marketplace for intellectual property, in particular its impact on
innovation incentives and competition concerns and the role of economic
analysis in this assessment. The Commission will accept comments, as
described above, until February 5, 2009. Comments addressing any of the
following questions would be particularly helpful.
1. How has the IP marketplace changed in the past five to ten
years? What changes are expected in the future? What aspects of the
patent system drive those changes? What is the impact of those changes
on innovation?
2. What are the new business models involving intellectual
property? What has motivated the development of these business models?
What is their impact on innovation?
3. What economic evidence is relevant when analyzing whether to
grant a permanent injunction following a finding of infringement? What
proof have courts required? How should the analysis take into account
the incentives to innovate provided by the patent system and the
benefits of competition? What is the appropriate remedy when the court
has denied a permanent injunction after a finding of infringement?
4. Do the legal rules governing patent damages result in awards
that appropriately compensate patentees? Are there circumstances in
which they result in overcompensation or undercompensation of
patentees? What evidence is there of the extent of these problems? What
information would be helpful to better assess whether damage awards
appropriately compensate patentees? Are courts and juries able to make
damages determinations with sufficient accuracy? To the extent that
there are problems resulting from the determination of damages for
patent infringement, how should they be addressed?
5. How have changes in willfulness doctrine changed the behavior of
patentees and potential infringers? Do recent changes in the law
adequately address the concerns with willfulness doctrine identified in
the October 2003 FTC IP Report?
6. How will changes in patent law rendered by Supreme Court and
Federal Circuit decisions of the past five years affect the value of
patents? How will these changes affect the operation of the
[[Page 70648]]
IP marketplace? How will they affect innovation and competition?
7. How does uncertainty regarding the validity and scope of patents
affect the operation of the IP marketplace? Does the current system
adequately fulfill the notice function of patents? How does uncertainty
influence the operation of the IP marketplace? What are the sources of
uncertainty that affect the value of patents and the operation of the
IP marketplace? What could be done to address them?
8. How transparent is the current IP marketplace? Can it be made
more transparent? Is that desirable?
9. During the past five years, what new learning has furthered the
understanding of the patent system and the IP marketplace?
By direction of the Commission.
Donald S. Clark,
Secretary.
[FR Doc. E8-27673 Filed 11-20-08: 8:45 am]
[BILLING CODE 6750-01-S]